14.08.2013 Views

The Impact of Microfinance on Household Welfare ... - X-Eye Design

The Impact of Microfinance on Household Welfare ... - X-Eye Design

The Impact of Microfinance on Household Welfare ... - X-Eye Design

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> <strong>Household</strong> <strong>Welfare</strong>:<br />

Case Study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a Savings Group in Lao PDR<br />

by<br />

K<strong>on</strong>gpasa Sengsouriv<strong>on</strong>g<br />

Master <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>sis<br />

Department <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Regi<strong>on</strong>al Cooperati<strong>on</strong> Policy Studies<br />

Graduate School <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Cooperati<strong>on</strong> Studies<br />

Kobe University<br />

Filed July 2006


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> <strong>Household</strong> <strong>Welfare</strong>:<br />

Case Study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a Savings Group in Lao PDR ∗<br />

K<strong>on</strong>gpasa Sengsouriv<strong>on</strong>g<br />

July 2006<br />

∗ Copyright © 2006, Master <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>sis submitted to the Department <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Regi<strong>on</strong>al Cooperati<strong>on</strong> Policy Studies,<br />

Graduate School <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Cooperati<strong>on</strong> Studies, Kobe University, Japan .<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> views and<br />

interpretati<strong>on</strong>s in this paper are those <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the author and do not necessarily reflect the positi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Kobe<br />

University. E-mail: s_k<strong>on</strong>gpasa@yahoo.com.


ACKNOWEDGEMENTS<br />

I am indeed indebted to my academic adviser, Associate Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>essor Koji KAWABATA<br />

for his insightful comments and support. I also would like to sincerely thank my two<br />

former academic advisers, Associate Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>essor Fumiharu MIENO who provided me with<br />

valued guidance, feedback and financial support for the follow-up survey in Laos, and<br />

Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>essor Hiroshi UENO who provided me <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> tremendous support during my first<br />

semester at the Graduate School <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Cooperati<strong>on</strong> Studies. I am very grateful<br />

to the critical questi<strong>on</strong>s and invaluable comments from both Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>essor Seiichi FUKUI<br />

and Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>essor CHEN Kuang-hui during the time <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> being examinati<strong>on</strong> committee.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> from Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>essor TAKAHASHI Motoki is gratefully acknowledged. I also<br />

wish to thank Dr. Shalini MATHUR for her assistance in editing and structuring my<br />

thesis.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, I would like to express my gratitude to the Lao Women’s Uni<strong>on</strong>,<br />

especially Ms. Sysay LEUDEDMOUNSONE (<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> President <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao Women’s Uni<strong>on</strong>),<br />

Ms. Boual<strong>on</strong>e VONGDALASENE (the President <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao Women’s Uni<strong>on</strong> at the<br />

Vientiane Capital), Ms. Saikham SENGKA (the President <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao Women’s Uni<strong>on</strong> at<br />

Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g city), and Ms. Khampane NAOVALARD (the Vice President <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao<br />

Women’s Uni<strong>on</strong> at Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g city) for their advice and support throughout the surveys.<br />

Thanks also to the Women and Community’s Empowering Project, particularly Mr.<br />

Khanth<strong>on</strong>e PHAMUANG (the Manager <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Women and Community’s Empowering<br />

Project), and the other staff <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the project for their support and cooperati<strong>on</strong> during the<br />

survey and for providing me with data <strong>on</strong> savings groups.<br />

ii


Furthermore, I am obliged to my former boss, Mr. Huw LESTER, Senior<br />

Manager <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> PricewaterhouseCoopers (Laos) Ltd, and Mrs. Rae DUNSTAN who edited<br />

and pro<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> read my paper. Special thanks to my beloved sister and brother, Ms.<br />

F<strong>on</strong>gchinda SENGSOURIVONG and Mr. Apisid SENGSOURIVONG, for their<br />

invaluable support and comments; and to my friends, Ms. Chanmany VONGLOKHAM,<br />

Mr. Paliph<strong>on</strong>epheth BOUARAVONG, Ms. Phoummaly SIRIPHOLDEJ, Ms. Visany<br />

PHOMSOMBATH, and the students <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the faculty <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omics and business<br />

management (FEBM) from the Nati<strong>on</strong>al University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos, for kindly helping me to<br />

c<strong>on</strong>duct surveys. I would also like to thank my friend, Mr. Bounth<strong>on</strong>e SOUKAVONG,<br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Lecturer at FEBM, for kindly providing the students to help me c<strong>on</strong>duct my<br />

survey. My gratitude to my friends, Mr. Santisouk PHOUNESAVATH and Mr. Buavanh<br />

VILAVONG for their invaluable comments; to Ms. Chansathith CHALEUNSHINH,<br />

Research Officer <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Nati<strong>on</strong>al Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research Institute, for providing me relevant data<br />

and arranging <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the surveys and to Ms. Daravanh VONGVIGIT, for kindly helping me<br />

<strong>on</strong> data processing. Many thanks to my Vietnamese friend, Ms. Nguyen Thi Thuy Vinh,<br />

for her helpful support <strong>on</strong> data processing and technical aspects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ec<strong>on</strong>ometric<br />

s<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>tware. In working through this research, I also have leant to appreciate positive<br />

externalities through discussi<strong>on</strong>s with my colleagues. I am thankful to them.<br />

Moreover, I would like to thank Japan Internati<strong>on</strong>al Cooperati<strong>on</strong> Agency (JICA)<br />

and Japan Internati<strong>on</strong>al Cooperati<strong>on</strong> Center (JICE) for the financial support during study<br />

in Japan. Finally, I would like to truly thank my beloved parents, my dear wife and my<br />

cute daughter for always supporting me.<br />

SENGSOURIVONG, K<strong>on</strong>gpasa. Kobe, Japan, July 2006.<br />

iii


EXECUTIVE SUMMARY<br />

Many countries recognize that micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance can play an important role in<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic development as <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the tools for poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>. Access to financial<br />

services is a major issue for both rural and urban areas <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos. C<strong>on</strong>sequently, the<br />

government <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos recognizes that access to rural finance and micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance could be<br />

<strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the major tools for poverty alleviati<strong>on</strong> and places micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance activities as <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

the priority programs for the agriculture and forestry sector in order to promote<br />

sustainable growth and poverty eradicati<strong>on</strong> under the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Growth and Poverty<br />

Eradicati<strong>on</strong> Strategy. Many studies have examined the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance<br />

and ec<strong>on</strong>omic development, but until now, <strong>on</strong>ly two key studies were undertaken in Laos.<br />

While these two studies made an important c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to this subject, they had some<br />

shortcomings as they did not correct for problems <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the self-selecti<strong>on</strong> and endogenous<br />

program placement.<br />

This paper surmounts these issues by adopting the methods used by Coleman<br />

(1999) to estimate the effects <strong>on</strong> household welfare or outcomes by the participati<strong>on</strong> in<br />

the savings group. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> survey was c<strong>on</strong>ducted in six villages in 2005 - 2006, in a semi-<br />

urban area <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos. All these villages had savings groups which were in operati<strong>on</strong> for<br />

various lengths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> time. Of these, three villages had savings groups operating for more<br />

than a year, and are called “old” savings groups. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> remaining three villages also started<br />

operating savings groups but these were in operati<strong>on</strong> for less than a year. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are called<br />

“new” savings groups. In the six villages, villagers were allowed to self-select to be<br />

iv


savings group members or n<strong>on</strong>members. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> survey sample included members and<br />

n<strong>on</strong>members in the six villages. Members who experienced benefits from joining the<br />

savings group by either obtaining a credit or receiving a dividend are called the<br />

“treatment” group, and those who have not benefited from the groups are called the<br />

“c<strong>on</strong>trol” group. All members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the “c<strong>on</strong>trol” group were relatively new members with<br />

an average membership <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 2.2 m<strong>on</strong>ths. Hence, the effects <strong>on</strong> savings group members in<br />

the treatment group can be compared with the savings group members in the c<strong>on</strong>trol<br />

group. In additi<strong>on</strong>, differences in the length <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> time that savings group program has been<br />

available to members in both treatment and c<strong>on</strong>trol groups is taken into account to obtain<br />

more precise impact estimates. Inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>members in all six villages allowed for<br />

the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> village fixed effect estimati<strong>on</strong> to c<strong>on</strong>trol the possibility that the order in which<br />

these six villages had savings group program placement is endogenous.<br />

With this kind <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> survey design, the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group program <strong>on</strong><br />

household outcomes can be straightforwardly estimated. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se positive outcomes include<br />

increase in household house value, household livestock producti<strong>on</strong> income, household<br />

agriculture producti<strong>on</strong> income, household rental expenses, and household educati<strong>on</strong><br />

expenses. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> results illustrate that the savings group participati<strong>on</strong> has large positive and<br />

significant effects <strong>on</strong> all <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these outcomes, except household yearly income from<br />

agriculture. However, this can largely be explained by issues relating to the robustness <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

the data for this indicator. In short, the participati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group can increase<br />

household asset, household income from self-employment activities and support the<br />

educati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> children.<br />

v


C<strong>on</strong>sequently, this paper’s findings have several important implicati<strong>on</strong>s. Firstly,<br />

the large positive impact savings group has <strong>on</strong> household asset suggest that micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance<br />

programs may improve household status in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> wealth. Sec<strong>on</strong>dly, the positive<br />

significant effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group <strong>on</strong> productivity, particularly livestock and<br />

agriculture in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> rental <strong>on</strong> rice fields, suggest that the savings group program may<br />

be a viable strategy for the poverty eradicati<strong>on</strong>. This is c<strong>on</strong>sistent with the Nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

Growth and Poverty Eradicati<strong>on</strong> Strategy (NGPES) (2004: 65) <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Government <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao<br />

PDR which recognizes the importance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance and has placed it as the <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

high priority projects for the agriculture and forestry development plan. Thirdly, the great<br />

positive influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group program <strong>on</strong> household educati<strong>on</strong> expenses<br />

suggests that micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance program may be <strong>on</strong>e viable strategy to reach the millennium<br />

development goals in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

vi


CHAPTER TITLE<br />

TABLE OF CONTENTS<br />

vii<br />

PAGE<br />

Title Page i<br />

Acknowledgements ii<br />

Executive Summary iv<br />

Table <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>tents vii<br />

List <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tables ix<br />

1 INTRODUCTION 1<br />

1.1 Issues 1<br />

1.2 Research Topic and Objective 5<br />

1.3 Hypothesis 5<br />

1.4 Methodology 6<br />

1.5 Structure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Paper 7<br />

2 MICROFINANCE IN LAOS 8<br />

2.1 Country Brief 8<br />

2.2 Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance in Laos 9<br />

3 LITERATURE REVIEW 19<br />

3.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> Studies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> Different Ec<strong>on</strong>omic and Social<br />

Indicators<br />

19<br />

3.2 Methodology 26<br />

4 ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK 31<br />

4.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>oretical Framework 31<br />

4.2 Model Specificati<strong>on</strong> and Methodology 36<br />

5 SURVEY DESIGN 46


5.1 Survey <strong>Design</strong> 47<br />

5.2 Data Descripti<strong>on</strong> 51<br />

6 EMPIRICAL RESULTS 52<br />

6.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>Household</strong> House Asset 55<br />

6.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Self-Employment Activities 59<br />

6.3 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Educati<strong>on</strong> 64<br />

7 CONCLUSION 67<br />

REFERENCES 71<br />

APPENDIX A 80<br />

Table 1: Descriptive Statistics for Variables <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Whole Sample Size 80<br />

Table 2: Descriptive Statistics for Variables by Treatment Group 84<br />

Table 3: Descriptive Statistics for Variables by C<strong>on</strong>trol Group 88<br />

Table 4: Descriptive Statistics for Variables by N<strong>on</strong>member 92<br />

Table 5: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Savings Group <strong>on</strong> <strong>Household</strong> House Value - GLS 96<br />

Table 6: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Savings Group <strong>on</strong> Yearly Self-Employment Income<br />

from Livestock – GLS<br />

100<br />

Table 7: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Savings Group <strong>on</strong> <strong>Household</strong> Yearly Self-<br />

Employment Income from Agriculture – GLS<br />

103<br />

Table 8: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Savings Group <strong>on</strong> <strong>Household</strong> M<strong>on</strong>thly Rental<br />

Expenditure – GLS<br />

106<br />

Table 9: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Savings Group <strong>on</strong> <strong>Household</strong> M<strong>on</strong>thly Educati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

Expenditure – GLS<br />

109<br />

APPENDIX B 112<br />

Case study: Savings Groups in Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g City 112<br />

viii


TABLE TITLE<br />

LIST OF TABLES<br />

ix<br />

PAGE<br />

2.1 Current Practices in Laos 16<br />

5.1 Sample Size 49


1.1 Issues<br />

CHAPTER 1<br />

INTRODUCTION<br />

Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance is significant source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> finance for poor, lower income people in<br />

developing countries. It provides the funding for these people to run their micro-business<br />

and to smooth their household’s c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>. Poor, lower income people have<br />

difficulties in obtaining finance from formal financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s such as commercial<br />

banks, due to barriers such as high collateral requirements and complicated applicati<strong>on</strong><br />

procedures (Yunus, 2001; and Hulme &Mosley, 1996). However, there is str<strong>on</strong>g demand<br />

for small-scale commercial financial services (for both credit and savings) am<strong>on</strong>g the<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omically active poor in developing countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se and other financial services help<br />

low-income people improve household and enterprise management, increase productivity,<br />

smooth income flows, enlarge and diversify their microenterprises, and increase their<br />

incomes (Robins<strong>on</strong>, 2001). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se effects were evident from a number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> impact studies<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance. Based <strong>on</strong> the recent studies <strong>on</strong> this subject, micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance has significant<br />

impact <strong>on</strong> income, expenditure, assets, educati<strong>on</strong>al status, health as well as gender<br />

empowerment.<br />

This positive impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> income was c<strong>on</strong>firmed in studies<br />

undertaken by Hulme and Mosley (1996); Mckernan (2002); Khandker et al. (1998);<br />

Copestake et al. (2001); Sichanth<strong>on</strong>gthip (2004); Shaw (2000); Mosley (2001); and<br />

Copestake (2002).<br />

1


Research by Pitt and Khander (1996 and 1998); and Khandker (2003) found that<br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance could increase household expenditure. Morduch (1998), however, argued<br />

that the eligible households that participated in the micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs have strikingly<br />

less c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> levels than the eligible households living in villages without the<br />

programs.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> positive impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> household assets was c<strong>on</strong>firmed in studies<br />

by M<strong>on</strong>tgomery et al. (1996); Pitt and Khandker (19996 and 1998); Mosley (2001); and<br />

Coleman (1999 and 2002). However, Mckernan (2002) found an inverse relati<strong>on</strong>ship<br />

between participati<strong>on</strong> in program and household assets. Mckernan also found that<br />

households with fewest assets benefit most from participating in a program.<br />

Research by Chowdhury and Bhuiya (2004); Holvoet (2004); and Pitt and<br />

Khandker (1996 and d1998) found that micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance has a positive effect <strong>on</strong> educati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Similarly, Chowdhury and Bhuiya (2004); Pitt and Khandker (1996); and Pitt et al.<br />

(1999) revealed that micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance has a positive impact <strong>on</strong> health. Furthermore, Hashemi<br />

et al. (1996); and Pitt and Khandker (1998) noted that micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance has positive effect <strong>on</strong><br />

women empowerment. However, there exists a counter argument that microcredit<br />

programs inflicted extreme pressure <strong>on</strong> women by forcing them down to meet difficult<br />

loan repayment schedules (Goetz and Gupta, 1996).<br />

Beside the micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance impact <strong>on</strong> the indicators menti<strong>on</strong>ed above, Kyophilav<strong>on</strong>g<br />

and Chaleunsinh, (2005), found that the behavior <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the village savings group members<br />

was changed as a result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> participating in a program. While previously savings were kept<br />

in the form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> gold, livestock, jewelry, deposits in the bank and savings at home,<br />

members now saved in the savings group.<br />

2


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao People’s Democratic Republic (Lao PDR) is <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poorest countries<br />

in East Asia in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an estimated per capita income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> US$ 390 in 2004 (World Bank<br />

Vientiane Office, 2006). Laos is classified by the United Nati<strong>on</strong> as a Least Developed<br />

Country (LDC). According to the World Bank Vientiane Office (2006), 71 per cent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Lao populati<strong>on</strong> lived <strong>on</strong> less than US$2 a day, and 23 per cent <strong>on</strong> less than US$1 a day in<br />

2004. In the same year, 34 per cent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the populati<strong>on</strong> lived under the nati<strong>on</strong>al poverty<br />

line; infant mortality was 82 per 1,000 live births; and life expectancy was approximately<br />

55 years.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sequently, the government <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos recognizes that access to rural finance and<br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance could be <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the major tools for poverty alleviati<strong>on</strong> and places<br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance activities as <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the priority programs for the agriculture and forestry<br />

sector in order to promote sustainable growth and poverty eradicati<strong>on</strong> under the Nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

Growth and Poverty Eradicati<strong>on</strong> Strategy (NGPES) (2004). Since 1987, the broad<br />

approach <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance, including in kind and in cash revolving role fund, has been<br />

implemented by numerous development projects which includes those <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> government.<br />

However, the micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance sector is still relatively new in Laos. Although d<strong>on</strong>ors have<br />

made a significant investment in the last few years in micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs, the sector<br />

is developing very slowly. About <strong>on</strong>e milli<strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omically active people potentially<br />

require access to formal or semi-formal micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance services. However, almost three<br />

quarters can not reach them. Approximately 300,000 people recently accessed loan and<br />

savings services. Only 21 per cent have access to microcredit from the formal sector. 33<br />

per cent are dependant <strong>on</strong> the semi-formal sector and project initiatives and the rest 46<br />

3


per cent are obtaining financial service from the informal sector (Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance Capacity<br />

Building and Research Programme, 2005).<br />

Very few empirical studies have c<strong>on</strong>ducted to examine the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance<br />

<strong>on</strong> individual, household, community, or instituti<strong>on</strong>al levels in Laos and to test whether<br />

or not micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance is <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> tools for poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>. One empirical study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao<br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> Saithani case 1 by Sichanth<strong>on</strong>gthip (2004) showed a positive impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

microcredit <strong>on</strong> income level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individual borrower. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> study involved evaluating the<br />

impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance program (village savings group) in a semi-urban area <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos<br />

using a questi<strong>on</strong>naire to collect primary household data from members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance program at two points <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> time (before and after borrowing) 2 .<br />

Sichanth<strong>on</strong>gthip reported the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <strong>on</strong> income by applying ec<strong>on</strong>ometric<br />

analysis. However, he did not c<strong>on</strong>trol for selecti<strong>on</strong> bias in the sample. Another study<br />

which was not aware with such bias is the study by Kyophilav<strong>on</strong>g and Chaleunsinh<br />

(2005) who estimated the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a village savings group in a semi-urban area <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos<br />

by c<strong>on</strong>ducting a survey for both members and n<strong>on</strong>members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the village savings group.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y presented <strong>on</strong>ly the means comparis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> many impact indicators for both members<br />

and n<strong>on</strong>members. Without the correcti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the selecti<strong>on</strong> bias problem, the results may<br />

overestimate the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the program.<br />

This study will attempt to evaluate the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs in Laos<br />

by correcting for the bias described above. This study also selected savings groups in<br />

Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g city as a case study. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> city is located in a semi-urban area <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Vientiane, the<br />

1 Saithani case is derived from that the Saithani Small and Rural Development Project (Saithani Project)<br />

which was established in 1996. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Project is a cooperative management between Lao Women’s Uni<strong>on</strong><br />

and the Foundati<strong>on</strong> for Integrated Agricultural Management (FIAM) (Sichanth<strong>on</strong>gthip, 2004:21).<br />

2 Data before the borrowing was collected by resp<strong>on</strong>dent recall.<br />

4


Capital <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos, and the program established as part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Women and Community’s<br />

Empowering Project. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> locati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the study was selected because most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings<br />

groups are located in and around the capital. Results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a recent survey found that most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

the 357 savings groups operating in Laos were located in and around Vientiane<br />

(Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance Capacity Building and Research Project (2003) cited in Chaleunsinh,<br />

2004:7).<br />

1.2 Research topic and objective<br />

Many studies examining the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance at the household level,<br />

enterprise level and macroec<strong>on</strong>omic level have shown a positive impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance<br />

<strong>on</strong> two sets <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> indicators – ec<strong>on</strong>omic and social indicators – in both developing and<br />

developed countries. However, such studies have not been widely c<strong>on</strong>ducted in Lao PDR.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, this paper will address this gap by examining the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance to<br />

household welfare or outcomes in Lao PDR. More specifically, it will investigate the<br />

impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings groups at the household level in a semi-urban area <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> primary objective <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a savings group in Laos is to improve the living status <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

borrowers and their families to bring them out <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poverty. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> main purpose <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this paper<br />

will be to evaluate the success <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group against their primary objective.<br />

1.3 Hypothesis<br />

Most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor people and lower income people join micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance program in Laos<br />

because they can access credit with specified interest rate which is lower than that<br />

obtained from the informal m<strong>on</strong>ey lender. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y can, thus, save m<strong>on</strong>ey. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, it is<br />

5


hypothesized that members with a l<strong>on</strong>g-term participati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the savings group may have<br />

better quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> life in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> wealth, income and expenses.<br />

1.4 Methodology<br />

To achieve the research objective, the author adopted the survey design and<br />

research methodology <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Coleman (1999) taking into account bias for self-selecti<strong>on</strong> and<br />

endogenous program placement which was not corrected in the previous studies relating<br />

to Laos. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> author c<strong>on</strong>ducted a survey <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 251 households in six villages in a semi-urban<br />

area <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos – Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g district which is located 16 kilometers from Vientiane, the<br />

Capital <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos. Of these, three villages had savings groups operating for more than a<br />

year, and are called “old” savings groups. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> remaining three villages also started<br />

operating savings groups but these were in operati<strong>on</strong> for less than a year. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are called<br />

“new” savings groups. In the six villages, villagers were allowed to self-select to be<br />

savings group members or n<strong>on</strong>members. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> survey sample included members and<br />

n<strong>on</strong>members in the six villages. Members who experienced benefits from joining the<br />

savings group by either obtaining a credit or receiving a dividend are called the<br />

“treatment” group, and those who have not benefited from the groups are called the<br />

“c<strong>on</strong>trol” group. All members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the “c<strong>on</strong>trol” group were relatively new members with<br />

an average membership <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 2.2 m<strong>on</strong>ths. Hence, the effects <strong>on</strong> savings group members in<br />

the treatment group can be compared with the savings group members in the c<strong>on</strong>trol<br />

group. In additi<strong>on</strong>, differences in the length <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> time that savings group program has been<br />

available to members in both treatment and c<strong>on</strong>trol groups is taken into account to obtain<br />

more precise impact estimates. Inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>members in all six villages allowed for<br />

6


the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> village fixed effect estimati<strong>on</strong> to c<strong>on</strong>trol the possibility that the order in which<br />

these six villages had savings group program placement is endogenous.<br />

1.5 Structure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the paper<br />

This paper is organized as follows:<br />

• Chapter 2 presents an overview <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance in Lao PDR.<br />

• Chapter 3 presents a literature review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> previous studies <strong>on</strong> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic and social indicators.<br />

• Chapter 4 discusses the theoretical framework and identifies the empirical<br />

modeling and estimati<strong>on</strong> methods to be used for this study.<br />

• Chapter 5 describes the survey design and data.<br />

• Chapter 6 outlines the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> empirical analysis.<br />

• Chapter 7 summarizes the results and draws policy implicati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

7


CHAPTER 2<br />

MICROFINANCE IN LAOS<br />

Many countries realize that micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance can play an important role in ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

development as <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the tools for poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> government <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos also<br />

recognizes that role and has placed micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance activities as <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the priority programs<br />

for the agriculture and forestry sector in order to promote sustainable growth and poverty<br />

eradicati<strong>on</strong> under the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Growth and Poverty Eradicati<strong>on</strong> Strategy (NGPES). This<br />

chapter will outline the general background <strong>on</strong> the development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance in Laos,<br />

provide an overview <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the current state <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> play in Laos in this area.<br />

2.1 Country Brief<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao People’s Democratic Republic (Lao PDR) is <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poorest countries<br />

in East Asia with an estimated per capita income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> US$ 390 in 2004 (World Bank<br />

Vientiane Office, 2006). Laos is classified by the United Nati<strong>on</strong> as a Least Developed<br />

Country (LDC). According to the World Bank Vientiane Office (2006), in 2004, 71 per<br />

cent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Lao populati<strong>on</strong> lived <strong>on</strong> less than US$2 a day, and 23 per cent <strong>on</strong> less than<br />

US$1 a day. In the same year, 34 per cent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the populati<strong>on</strong> lived under the nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

poverty line; infant mortality was 82 per 1,000 live births; and life expectancy was<br />

approximately 55 years.<br />

In 2004, Laos had a populati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> around 5.8 milli<strong>on</strong> and a land area <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 236,800<br />

square kilometers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> country is characterized by a high degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> geographic, cultural<br />

8


and linguistic diversity with very poor infrastructure. Moreover, villages, particularly<br />

those populated by ethnic minority groups, tend to be extremely isolated and practice<br />

subsistence agriculture. Laos is also a landlocked country which is located in the center<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Mek<strong>on</strong>g regi<strong>on</strong>, bordered by Thailand, Vietnam, Southern China, Cambodia and<br />

Myanmar, <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> which, the first three are experiencing rapid ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. Nevertheless,<br />

Laos has significant ec<strong>on</strong>omic potential because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its rich natural resources (such as<br />

forestry, minerals and hydro-electric power) and its proximity to major Asian ec<strong>on</strong>omies.<br />

Agriculture is the major ec<strong>on</strong>omic sector c<strong>on</strong>tributing 51 per cent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> GDP and employing<br />

80 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the labor force. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> industry sector accounts for 23 per cent and services<br />

for 26 per cent (World Bank Vientiane Office, 2006).<br />

2.2 Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance in Laos<br />

Since 1987, the broad approach <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance in Laos (including in kind and in<br />

cash revolving role fund) has been implemented by numerous development projects<br />

which include those initiated by the government. However, the micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance sector is still<br />

relatively new in Laos. Although d<strong>on</strong>ors have made a significant investment in the last<br />

few years in micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs, the sector is developing very slowly. About <strong>on</strong>e<br />

milli<strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omically active people potentially require access to formal or semi-formal<br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance services. However, almost three quarters cannot reach them. Approximately<br />

300,000 people recently accessed loan and savings services. Only 21 per cent have access<br />

to microcredit from the formal sector, 33 per cent are dependant <strong>on</strong> the semi-formal<br />

sector and project initiatives and the rest 46 per cent are obtaining financial services from<br />

the informal sector (Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance Capacity Building and Research Programme, 2005).<br />

9


This secti<strong>on</strong> will briefly describe the development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance providers 3 which c<strong>on</strong>sist <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the formal, semiformal and informal sectors.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> informati<strong>on</strong> is sourced from Enterplan (2003).<br />

2.2.1 Formal sector<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> formal banking system in Laos c<strong>on</strong>sists <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>:<br />

• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Bank <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos (the central bank);<br />

• Three state-owned banks (the Banque pour le Commerce Exterieur Lao<br />

(BCEL), Lao Development Bank (LDB) 4 , and the Agricultural Promoti<strong>on</strong><br />

Bank (APB));<br />

• Three joint venture banks (Joint Development Bank, Lao-Viet Bank and<br />

Vientiane Commercial Bank);<br />

• Six foreign commercial banks with branch <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fices and <strong>on</strong>e foreign<br />

commercial bank with a representative <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fice (FCBs) 5 .<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> headquarters <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> each bank are located in Vientiane. APB is the largest bank<br />

in term <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> branch network in Lao PDR. It has <strong>on</strong>e head <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fice in Vientiane, 18 branches<br />

in the 17 provincial capitals and Vientiane Capital City, and 55 sub-service units at the<br />

district level. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> head <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fice <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> LDB is also located in Vientiane and it has 17 branches<br />

(<strong>on</strong>e in each province). BCEL has three branches. Lao-Viet Bank has <strong>on</strong>e branch in<br />

3 This secti<strong>on</strong> borrows extensively from Enterplan (2003).<br />

4 It was merged from two state-owned banks: Lao May Bank and Lane Xang Bank.<br />

5 Public Bank (Malaysia), Bangkok Bank, Bank <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ayudhya, Krung Thai Bank, Siam Commercial Bank,<br />

Thai Military Bank (all Thai Bank) all <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> which have branch <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fices in Vientiane. Standard Chartered Bank<br />

has a representative <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fice and <strong>on</strong>ly provides <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fshore guarantee facilities for overseas clients doing<br />

business in Laos.<br />

10


Champasack province. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rest (JVBs and FCBs) have no branches and no provincial<br />

outreach, and <strong>on</strong>ly operate in the area around Vientiane municipality.<br />

Practically, <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>e formal financial instituti<strong>on</strong>, APB 6 , has a large outreach and a<br />

true track record in rural finance. APB was established by Decree in 1992 (Decree 92/PM<br />

1992) to assist the development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the agricultural sector in Laos. Since March 2000,<br />

APB has been largely under the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Decree <strong>on</strong> Commercial Banks<br />

(Decree02/PR 2000) after operating under that separate mandate. In April 2002, APB had<br />

about 130,000 borrowers. Of these, about 123,000 were in groups (group lending). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

activities <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> APB have focused <strong>on</strong> the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> subsidized loans which use funds from<br />

the government and d<strong>on</strong>ors.<br />

2.2.2 Semiformal sector<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> semiformal financial sector in Laos is poorly developed. In this sector,<br />

activities may be classified in two categories: micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance initiatives and illustrative<br />

Internati<strong>on</strong>al N<strong>on</strong> Government Organizati<strong>on</strong> (INGO) initiatives.<br />

A. Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance Initiatives<br />

Many micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance initiatives provide micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance in urban and rural areas <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Laos through program such as the Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance Project, Cooperative de Credit de<br />

Soutien aux Producteurs (CCSP), Project de Developpement Rural du District de<br />

Ph<strong>on</strong>gsaly (PDDP), the Rural Development Cooperative (RDC), and Credit Uni<strong>on</strong> Pilot<br />

Project.<br />

6<br />

Lane Xang Bank before merging with Lao May Bank also provided micro lending with a focus <strong>on</strong> microtraders<br />

(Bank <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Lao PDR, 2002: 31).<br />

11


(1) <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance project<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> United Nati<strong>on</strong>s Capital Development Fund (UNCDF) and the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Development Programme (UNDP) with cooperati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Government <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos launched<br />

the micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance project in late 1997. This project ran micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance activities in<br />

Oudomxay and Sayaboury Provinces using the group lending methodology. It also<br />

includes the Sihom Project Savings and Credit Scheme (SIPSACRES) – an urban credit<br />

and savings cooperative founded under UNDP project in 1995. However, the UNDP and<br />

UNCDF did not provide funding for this project after 2002. Now, the Lao government<br />

manages the project 7 . While data for 2002 is unavailable, estimated data for 2000 showed<br />

that the micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance project serves about 3,525 clients in total in October 2000 (United<br />

Nati<strong>on</strong>s Capital Development Fund, 2001).<br />

(2) Cooperative de Credit de Soutien aux Producteurs (CCSP)<br />

CCSP was established in 1996 <strong>on</strong> the initiative <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a group <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao entrepreneurs. It<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sists <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> nine member-owned cooperatives. Microcredit provided to their clients in the<br />

vicinity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Vientiane is for the purposed <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> agriculture, handicraft, small industry and<br />

services. CCSP also accepts savings from member and issues loan to members secured by<br />

group guarantee and compulsory savings. In September 2002, there were about 1,000<br />

active savers and about 650 active borrowers in this initiative.<br />

(3) Project de Developpement Rural du District de Ph<strong>on</strong>gsaly (PDDP)<br />

PDDP was formed in 1997. It runs village banks for farmers in 57 villages in<br />

Ph<strong>on</strong>gsaly city with the support from Agence Francais Developpement (AFD). PDDP<br />

also requires compulsory savings from their members and leverages these with AFD<br />

7 For the <strong>on</strong>es operating in Sayaboury and Oudomxay provinces are recently under the provincial<br />

government authorities. SIPSACRES is currently under the supervisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Finance Department, Vientiane<br />

Capital.<br />

12


funds. In March 2003, about 2,350 borrowers received a loan from PDDP. In this<br />

initiative, loans are provided for cash crops, livestock, handicraft and petty trade and it<br />

applies a joint liability system for loan guarantee.<br />

(4) Rural Development Cooperative(RDC)<br />

RDC began running its activities in August 2001 when it received the funds from<br />

the Vientiane Municipal Development Fund. Its operati<strong>on</strong> is implemented in thirty<br />

villages in Vientiane Capital City. Its services include both credit and savings. Loans are<br />

issued for different kinds <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities such as agriculture, handicraft and trade.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se loans require physical collateral and a 20 per cent savings deposit for guarantee.<br />

RDC had between 400 and 500 borrowers in 2003.<br />

(5) Credit Uni<strong>on</strong> Pilot Project<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Credit Uni<strong>on</strong> Pilot Project is <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the subprojects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Asian Development<br />

Bank TA cluster 3413 – LAO: Rural Finance Development. In March 2003, the savings<br />

and credit uni<strong>on</strong>s (SCUs) were established in Vientiane, Savanakhet and Luang Prabang<br />

Provinces. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> three pilot credit uni<strong>on</strong>s have licensing as a c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ADB<br />

Banking Sector Reform Programme Loan (BSRPL).<br />

B. Illustrative INGO initiatives<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong> to the micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance initiatives, there are about 1,600 village revolving<br />

funds (VRFs) that have been supported by d<strong>on</strong>ors and NGOs (Bank <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Lao PDR,<br />

2002: 31).<br />

Internati<strong>on</strong>al N<strong>on</strong> Government Organizati<strong>on</strong>s (INGOs) use village revolving<br />

funds (VRFs) to widely provide financial services in the rural areas. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se organizati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

13


tend to focus <strong>on</strong> the operati<strong>on</strong> in the areas which are not covered by banks including the<br />

APB. In these areas, villagers can <strong>on</strong>ly access to credit from friends, family members,<br />

and m<strong>on</strong>eylenders. Around 35 INGOs and a few bilateral and multilateral agencies are<br />

supporting rural development projects in Laos. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se projects have set up cash or in-kind<br />

funds for villagers as part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their integrated programmes. Assistance is provided for<br />

agricultural equipment, gravity water and irrigati<strong>on</strong> supplies, seeds, rice banks for food<br />

security, animal banks, and medicinal drug fund. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> projects depend <strong>on</strong> subsidized<br />

credit and when this credit finishes when the project ends. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is rarely any local<br />

resource mobilizati<strong>on</strong>. As a result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the above, a substantial number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> projects are not<br />

sustainable.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao Women’s Uni<strong>on</strong> (LWU) is a key intermediary for INGOs rural financial<br />

projects. LWU was established in 1955 and is a mass organizati<strong>on</strong> which has been<br />

implemented at three levels – district, provincial and nati<strong>on</strong>al. LWU operates in every<br />

village through the country. It is active in a significant share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> INGOs projects as an<br />

intermediary, an organizer, and as the Lao Government partner. Due to its reach into the<br />

villages, LWU has frequently been the implementing agent or partner for INGO-<br />

supported projects.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong> to LWU, there are three more mass organizati<strong>on</strong>s 8 and five<br />

government <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fices 9 at district and provincial level to run micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs<br />

throughout the country (Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance Capacity Building and Research Programme,<br />

2005).<br />

8<br />

Lao Youth Uni<strong>on</strong>, Lao Fr<strong>on</strong>t for Nati<strong>on</strong>al C<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> Office and Federati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Trade Uni<strong>on</strong>.<br />

9<br />

Agriculture Office, Planning and Investment Office, Health Office, Labour and Social <strong>Welfare</strong> Office,<br />

and Finance Office.<br />

14


In additi<strong>on</strong>, there are many NGOs running micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance initiatives in Laos<br />

including CARE, CONSORTIUM, CUSO, Menn<strong>on</strong>ite Central Committee (MCC), Save<br />

the Children Australia (SCA).<br />

2.2.3 Informal sector<br />

This sector comprises m<strong>on</strong>eylenders, rotating savings and credit schemes which<br />

locally known as Houai (daily, weekly, and m<strong>on</strong>thly), traders and rich farmers.<br />

According to Bagchi et al. (2002), inter-household loans are important am<strong>on</strong>g rural<br />

households and most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these loans are made in-kind. Nevertheless, rotating savings and<br />

credit (Houai) is a significant source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loan m<strong>on</strong>ey for investment or emergency needs in<br />

the urban or semi-urban areas.<br />

M<strong>on</strong>eylender<br />

According to the Bank <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Lao PDR (2002), the role <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>eylenders in both<br />

urban and rural areas is estimated to be quite important – approximately 50 per cent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

rural villages appear to have access to m<strong>on</strong>ey lender services. Most pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>essi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

m<strong>on</strong>eylenders operate close to the markets and lend for quick turnover activities.<br />

According to pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>essi<strong>on</strong>al observati<strong>on</strong>, rates have been stable for the last few years<br />

ranging from 10 and 30 per cent per m<strong>on</strong>th with lower interest rates in urban areas due to<br />

competiti<strong>on</strong>. Supplier credit for agricultural inputs is rare. Some foreign suppliers across<br />

the Mek<strong>on</strong>g River accept precious metals as collateral for merchandise purchases.<br />

As described above, there are many different approaches to micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance in Laos.<br />

Bagchi et al. (2002) analyzed each micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance practice in Laos and provide<br />

commentary <strong>on</strong> each type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> initiative. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se comments are summarized in Table 2.1.<br />

15


Table 2.1: Current practices in Laos 10<br />

No. Approach/<br />

Implementing agencies<br />

Limitati<strong>on</strong>s/ Challenges<br />

Models GoL/Ministry/ Bank INGOs Bi and or<br />

Provincial<br />

Multilateral<br />

Authority/<br />

Mass<br />

organizati<strong>on</strong><br />

agency<br />

1 Instituti<strong>on</strong>al √ √ • Not targeting poor people<br />

methodology<br />

• Not flexible enough<br />

(solidarity<br />

methodology<br />

focused <strong>on</strong><br />

instituti<strong>on</strong>al<br />

sustainability)<br />

• Limited outreach<br />

• Rural households do not have<br />

access to financial services<br />

2 Credit uni<strong>on</strong> √ √ • Lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>fidence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> people<br />

as a depositor<br />

• Limited outreach<br />

• Rural households do not have<br />

access to financial services<br />

• Lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> skilled human<br />

resources<br />

3 Direct bank<br />

√ • Accessibility is difficult<br />

operati<strong>on</strong><br />

because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> lots <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> paper work<br />

and formality<br />

• Lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>fidence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> people<br />

as a depositor<br />

• Limited outreach<br />

• Rural households do not have<br />

access to financial services<br />

• Lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> skilled human<br />

resources<br />

• Does not disclose its<br />

financial informati<strong>on</strong> or audit<br />

results to the public<br />

4 Co-operative √ • Limited outreach<br />

• Rural households do not have<br />

access to financial services<br />

5 Self help group √ √ √ • Not properly designed<br />

• Ownership is big challenge<br />

• Most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the time village elite<br />

people have easy access to<br />

funds<br />

• Often poorer people<br />

excluded from the benefits<br />

• Highly subsidized<br />

10 Table 2.1 is sourced from the market research study d<strong>on</strong>e by Bagchi et al. (2002).<br />

16


No. Approach/<br />

Implementing agencies<br />

Limitati<strong>on</strong>s/ Challenges<br />

Models GoL/Ministry/ Bank INGOs Bi and or<br />

Provincial<br />

Multilateral<br />

Authority/<br />

Mass<br />

organizati<strong>on</strong><br />

agency<br />

6 Village or √ √ √ √ • Not properly designed<br />

community<br />

• Ownership is big challenge<br />

bank<br />

• Most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the time village elite<br />

people have easy access to the<br />

fund<br />

• Often poorer people excluded<br />

from the benefits<br />

• Emphasis <strong>on</strong> credit rather than<br />

savings<br />

• Sustainability is questi<strong>on</strong>ed<br />

7 Informal kinds √ √ √ • Mainly introduced for food<br />

(cereal and<br />

security<br />

animal bank)<br />

• No cash transacti<strong>on</strong>s made<br />

initiatives<br />

• Not financial services<br />

• Pushing back towards the n<strong>on</strong><br />

cash ec<strong>on</strong>omy<br />

• Highly subsidized<br />

• Very informally organized<br />

• Very limited opti<strong>on</strong> for local<br />

resources mobilizati<strong>on</strong><br />

8 Village √ √ √ • Ownership is a questi<strong>on</strong><br />

Revolving Fund<br />

• Often poorly designed<br />

• Most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the time village elite<br />

people have easy access to funds<br />

• Often poorer people excluded<br />

from benefits<br />

• Emphasis <strong>on</strong> credit rather than<br />

savings<br />

• Highly subsidized<br />

• Leadership is a crucial factor<br />

• Sustainability is questi<strong>on</strong>ed<br />

Source: Annex 5 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Bagchi et al. (2002).<br />

Although the practice <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance in Laos is still new and at an early stage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

development, this study aims to examine the influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> household’s<br />

outcomes. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, the rest <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the paper will c<strong>on</strong>duct an in-depth investigati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

17


effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings groups <strong>on</strong> household welfare or outcomes to determine whether or not<br />

the household’s status improves with access to micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance.<br />

18


CHAPTER 3<br />

LITERATURE REVIEW<br />

Most existing studies <strong>on</strong> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance examine two sets <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

indicators 11 – ec<strong>on</strong>omic and social indicators – at different levels 12 . Despite the variati<strong>on</strong><br />

in the methods used and the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> studies c<strong>on</strong>ducted in various countries, the main<br />

impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance impact is <strong>on</strong> change in income, expenditure, assets, educati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

status, health as well as gender empowerment. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> studies that have examined the impact<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> these indicators are discussed below.<br />

3.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> studies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> different ec<strong>on</strong>omic and social indicators<br />

3.1.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> studies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> income<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> effect <strong>on</strong> income has been analyzed at the individual, household and<br />

enterprise levels. Hulme and Mosley (1996), c<strong>on</strong>ducted various studies <strong>on</strong> different<br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs in numerous countries, and found str<strong>on</strong>g evidence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the positive<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship between access to a credit and the borrower’s level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> authors<br />

indicated that the middle and upper poor received more benefits from income-generating<br />

credit initiatives than the poorest. McKernan (2002), moreover, evaluated three<br />

significant microcredit programs in Bangladesh and discovered that the pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>it for self-<br />

employed activities <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> households can be increased by program participati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se<br />

11 Ec<strong>on</strong>omic indicators are normally measurements for micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance impact as income, level and patterns<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> expenditure, c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> and assets. Social indicators to measure the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance became<br />

popular in the early 1980s as educati<strong>on</strong>al status, access to health services, nutriti<strong>on</strong>al levels, anthropometric<br />

measures and c<strong>on</strong>traceptive use, for example (Hulme, 2000).<br />

12 Hulme (2000) identified levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> assessment in different units as individual, enterprise, household,<br />

community, instituti<strong>on</strong>al impacts and household ec<strong>on</strong>omic portfolio such as households, enterprise,<br />

individual and community.<br />

19


programs were also examined at the village-level impacts in the study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Khandker et<br />

al.(1998) which showed that they have positive impact <strong>on</strong> average households’ annual<br />

income, especially in the rural n<strong>on</strong>-farm sector. Copestake et al. (2001), estimated the<br />

effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an urban credit programme – a group-based microcredit programme – in Zambia,<br />

and found that microcredit has a significant impact <strong>on</strong> the growth in enterprise pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>it and<br />

household income in case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the borrowers who have received a sec<strong>on</strong>d loan.<br />

Sichanth<strong>on</strong>gthip’s study (2004) also pointed to a positive impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> microcredit <strong>on</strong> the<br />

income level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individual borrowers. This can be seen from the higher m<strong>on</strong>thly income<br />

earned after the member accessed credit, in the empirical study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong><br />

Saithani case. Shaw (2000) studied two micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance instituti<strong>on</strong>s (MFIs) in Southeastern<br />

Sri Lanka and showed that the less poor clients’ microbusiness that accessed loans from<br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs could earn more income than those <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor do. Mosley (2001)<br />

evaluated the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loans provided by two urban and two rural MFIs <strong>on</strong> poverty in<br />

Bolivia. He found that the net impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance from all instituti<strong>on</strong>s, at the average<br />

level, was positive in relati<strong>on</strong> to borrowers’ income, even though that net impact for<br />

poorer borrowers might be less than the net impact <strong>on</strong> richer borrowers. Copestake<br />

(2002) c<strong>on</strong>ducted the case study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Zambian Copperbelt, applying the village bank<br />

model to investigate the effect <strong>on</strong> income distributi<strong>on</strong> at the household and enterprise<br />

levels. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> study showed that the impact <strong>on</strong> income distributi<strong>on</strong> depends <strong>on</strong> who obtains<br />

the loan, who move <strong>on</strong> to larger loans and who exits the program: group dynamics was<br />

also an important factor. As he discovered, “Some initial levelling up <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> business<br />

incomes was found, but the more marked overall effect am<strong>on</strong>g borrowers was <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income<br />

polarizati<strong>on</strong>.”(Copestake, 2002: 743).<br />

20


3.1.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> studies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> expenditure<br />

Expenditure is another indicator to measure the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance. Pitt and<br />

Khandker (1996 and 1998) estimated the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> microcredit obtained by both males<br />

and females for the Grameen Bank and two other group-based microcredit programs in<br />

Bangladesh <strong>on</strong> various indicators. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y showed that the clients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the programs could<br />

gain from participating micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs in many ways. It can be seen that income<br />

per capita c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> could be increased by accessing a loan from a microcredit<br />

program such as the Grameen Bank. Khandker (2003) also c<strong>on</strong>ducted research <strong>on</strong> the<br />

l<strong>on</strong>g-run impacts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> household c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> and poverty in Bangladesh<br />

by identifying types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> impact in six household’s outcomes as outlined bellow:<br />

• Per capita total expenditure;<br />

• Per capita food expenditure;<br />

• Per capita n<strong>on</strong>-food expenditure;<br />

• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> incidence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> moderate and extreme poverty;<br />

• <strong>Household</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-land assets<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> author found that the micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> male borrowing were much weaker<br />

than the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female borrowing and there was decrease in return to borrowing all the<br />

time. Moreover, he noted that the impact <strong>on</strong> food expenditure was less pr<strong>on</strong>ounced than<br />

the <strong>on</strong>e <strong>on</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-food expenditure. Besides, he showed that the poorest gained benefits<br />

from micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance and micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance had a sustainable impact in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poverty<br />

reducti<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g program participants. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the author discovered that there was<br />

spillover effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance to reduce poverty at the village level. In c<strong>on</strong>trast, the<br />

impact was less noticeable in reducing moderate rather than extreme poverty. Morduch<br />

21


(1998), however, argued that the eligible households that participated in these three<br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs have strikingly less c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> levels than the eligible<br />

households living in villages without the programs.<br />

3.1.3 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> studies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> wealth<br />

A further indicator <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance is wealth. M<strong>on</strong>tgomery et al.<br />

(1996) examined the performance and impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> two micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs in<br />

Bangladesh. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y found that there were positive impacts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a microcredit program, such<br />

as the Bangladesh Rural Advancement Committee’s (BRAC’s) Rural Development<br />

Program (RDP), <strong>on</strong> both enterprise and household assets. Clearly, even though total value<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household assets had a slight increase after the borrowers obtained last loans, there had<br />

significant increase in the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> productive assets. Pitt and Khandker (1996 and 1998)<br />

also noted that the microcredit had a positive impact <strong>on</strong> women’s n<strong>on</strong>-land assets. Mosley<br />

(2001) also pointed out that there was positive impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> asset levels. He<br />

further stated that accumulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> asset and income status was generally highly<br />

correlated, which led to extreme correlati<strong>on</strong> between income poverty and asset poverty.<br />

Coleman (1999) investigated the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a village bank <strong>on</strong> borrower welfare in<br />

Northeast Thailand. He found that there was a slight impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> program loans <strong>on</strong> clients’<br />

welfare. However, he discovered that the village bank had a positive and significant<br />

impact <strong>on</strong> the accumulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> women’s wealth, particularly landed wealth but this result<br />

included bias from measured impact (discussed in methodology below). In c<strong>on</strong>trary to the<br />

positive results, Mckernan (2002) found an inverse relati<strong>on</strong>ship between participati<strong>on</strong> in<br />

22


program and household assets. Mckernan also found that households with fewest assets<br />

benefit most from participating in a program.<br />

3.1.4 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> studies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> educati<strong>on</strong>al status<br />

Many impact studies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance have focused <strong>on</strong> educati<strong>on</strong>al status.<br />

Chowdhury and Bhuiya (2004), studied the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance program, BRAC<br />

poverty alleviati<strong>on</strong> program, in Bangladesh, and found that both member and n<strong>on</strong>-<br />

member groups <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> BRAC had improved in educati<strong>on</strong>al performance. However, the<br />

BRAC member households benefited much more than poor n<strong>on</strong>-member households.<br />

Furthermore, girls gained more than boys. Holvoet (2004) investigated the effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> childhood educati<strong>on</strong> by examining two micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs in South<br />

India – <strong>on</strong>e with direct bank-borrower credit and another <strong>on</strong>e with group mediated credit.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> author showed that loans to women, through women’s groups, had a significant<br />

positive impact <strong>on</strong> schooling and literacy for girls, whereas it remained mainly<br />

unchangeable in the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> boys. However, in case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct individual bank-borrower<br />

lending, there was no improvement in educati<strong>on</strong>al inputs and outputs for children. Pitt<br />

and Khandker (1996) found that a credit to the participants provided by a micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance<br />

instituti<strong>on</strong> like the Grameen Bank, could grow school enrolment for children. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y found,<br />

for example, that in case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grameen Bank and Bangladesh Rural Development<br />

Board’s (BRDB) Rural Development RD-12 program, credit lending to women had a<br />

significantly positive impact <strong>on</strong> schooling for boys (Pitt and Khandker, 1998).<br />

23


3.1.5 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> studies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> health<br />

Indicators related health issues are also applied as proxies to examine the impact<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance. Chowdhury and Bhuiya (2004) found that micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance program, led to<br />

a good improvement in child survival and nutriti<strong>on</strong>al status. Pitt and Khandker (1996)<br />

also noted that there was a rise in c<strong>on</strong>traceptive use and decrease in fertility in case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

participants obtaining a credit provided by the Grameen Bank. However, there was no<br />

evidence to prove that an increase in c<strong>on</strong>traceptive use or a decrease in fertility resulted<br />

from the participati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> women in group-based credit programs. But fertility reducti<strong>on</strong><br />

was observed and c<strong>on</strong>traceptive use slightly increased in case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> men’s participati<strong>on</strong> (Pitt<br />

et al., 1999).<br />

3.1.6 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> studies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> empowerment<br />

Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance also leads to the empowerment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> women. Hashemi et al. (1996)<br />

studied two main micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs in Bangladesh, the Grameen Bank and the<br />

Bangladesh Rural Advancement Committee (BRAC). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y noted that the participati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

the programs had important positive impacts <strong>on</strong> eight different dimensi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> women’s<br />

empowerment:<br />

• Mobility,<br />

• Ec<strong>on</strong>omic security,<br />

• Ability to make small purchases,<br />

• Ability to make larger purchases,<br />

• Involvement in major household decisi<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

24


• Relative freedom from dominati<strong>on</strong> by the family (especially, women’s<br />

ownership <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> productive assets),<br />

• Political and legal awareness,<br />

• Participati<strong>on</strong> in public protest and political campaigning.<br />

In another study, Pitt and Khandker (1998) found that the behavior <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor households<br />

was significantly changed in case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> women’s participati<strong>on</strong> in the program credit, in<br />

Bangladesh. It, for example, could be seen that every 100 additi<strong>on</strong>al taka credit provided<br />

to women by the microcredit programs, namely the Grameen Bank, BRAC and BRDB,<br />

increased yearly expenditure for household c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> by 18 taka, whereas that<br />

provided to men from the same programs grew yearly household c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong><br />

expenditure by 11 taka. However, there exists a counter argument that microcredit<br />

programs inflicted extreme pressure <strong>on</strong> women by forcing them down to meet difficult<br />

loan repayment schedules (Goetz and Gupta, 1996).<br />

Besides the micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance impact <strong>on</strong> the indicators menti<strong>on</strong>ed above, <strong>on</strong>e study<br />

tried to examine how the savings group in Laos affects the behavior <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> member <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a<br />

village savings group. It showed that the behavior <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the village savings group members<br />

was changed as a result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> participating in a program. While previously savings were kept<br />

in the form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> gold, livestock, jewelry, deposits in the bank, and savings at home,<br />

members now saved in the savings group (Kyophilav<strong>on</strong>g and Chaleunsinh, 2005).<br />

Different methodologies have been adopted to analyze the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance<br />

programs. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are discussed in the next secti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

25


3.2 Methodology<br />

Empirical studies <strong>on</strong> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance can be distinguished into two<br />

main groups: those that were not c<strong>on</strong>cerned about selecti<strong>on</strong> bias problem 13 and those that<br />

were. A large number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> impact studies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs did not take into<br />

account selecti<strong>on</strong> bias. According to Chen’ s review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 11 impact studies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grameen<br />

Bank in Bangladesh, no study corrected the selecti<strong>on</strong> bias (Chen (1992) cited in Coleman<br />

1999, p.109). Shaw (2004) also studied two micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs in Sri Lanka, and<br />

used a questi<strong>on</strong>naire and c<strong>on</strong>ducted interviews in <strong>on</strong>e semi-urban and two rural groups.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> author presented <strong>on</strong>ly median comparis<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> client incomes am<strong>on</strong>g four household<br />

income groups (extreme poor, poor, near-poor and n<strong>on</strong>poor), at time <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their first loan<br />

(June 1994) and at the time the research was c<strong>on</strong>ducted (June1999). However, he did not<br />

take into account selecti<strong>on</strong> bias. Sichanth<strong>on</strong>gthip (2004) evaluated the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a<br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance program <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the village savings group in a semi-urban area <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos and used<br />

a questi<strong>on</strong>naire to collect primary household data from members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance<br />

program at two points <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> time (before and after borrowing). He reported the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

impact <strong>on</strong> income by applying ec<strong>on</strong>ometric analysis. On the other hand, he also did not<br />

c<strong>on</strong>trol for selecti<strong>on</strong> bias. Another study which also did not take into account such bias is<br />

the study by Kyophilav<strong>on</strong>g and Chaleunsinh (2005) who estimated the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a village<br />

savings group in a semi-urban area <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos by c<strong>on</strong>ducting a survey for both member and<br />

n<strong>on</strong>member <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> village savings group. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y presented <strong>on</strong>ly a comparis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mean<br />

values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> many impact indicators for both members and n<strong>on</strong>members.<br />

13 As Holvoet (2004: 32) noted, “Selecti<strong>on</strong> bias may occur because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>random program placement,<br />

through selecti<strong>on</strong> by program staff, or because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> self-selecti<strong>on</strong> by program participants”. For further<br />

details, please read more in Baker (2000), and Greene (2000). For numerous discussi<strong>on</strong>s for methods to<br />

correct that bias, please refer to Heckman and Robb (1985), M<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fitt (1991), and Ravalli<strong>on</strong> (2005).<br />

26


A number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> researchers, however, have attempted to correct the selecti<strong>on</strong> bias.<br />

Hashemi et al. (1996) evaluated the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> rural credit programs in Bangladesh by<br />

undertaking ethnographic research in six villages during the period 1991-94 and<br />

c<strong>on</strong>ducting a survey in late 1992. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> authors classified their sample into four groups<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sisting <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>:<br />

• Grameen Bank members,<br />

• BRAC members,<br />

• N<strong>on</strong>members living in the Grameen Bank villages (who would have been<br />

eligible to join either BRAC or Grameen Bank),<br />

• A comparis<strong>on</strong> group living in villages without the Grameen Bank or<br />

BRAC programs but who would have qualified to join the credit programs.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y also tried to address the possibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> selecti<strong>on</strong> bias by including n<strong>on</strong>participants<br />

and participants in Grameen Bank villages and comparing them with women living in<br />

villages without microcredit programs.<br />

In c<strong>on</strong>trast, Hashemi et al. (1996) did not c<strong>on</strong>trol for possibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> endogenous<br />

program placement, even though, the authors presented the effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> credit program <strong>on</strong><br />

eight dimensi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowerment by applying logistic regressi<strong>on</strong> models as menti<strong>on</strong>ed<br />

in secti<strong>on</strong> 3.1.6 above.<br />

Hulme and Mosley (1996) also tried to solve for selecti<strong>on</strong> bias by studying<br />

different credit programs in a number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> countries. In their study, they included eight<br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance instituti<strong>on</strong>s which provide group lending. Of these eight instituti<strong>on</strong>s, two<br />

were used a c<strong>on</strong>trol group in the case a loan had been approved for participants but they<br />

had not yet received any amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the loan. However, <strong>on</strong>ly the means <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> different<br />

27


outcome variables for both treatment and c<strong>on</strong>trol groups were introduced. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re were no<br />

statistical analyses <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the differences between the two groups. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the possibility<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> endogenous program placement could not be c<strong>on</strong>trolled with their available data<br />

(Coleman, 1999: 109).<br />

Recently, many papers <strong>on</strong> the evaluati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs have adopted<br />

an ec<strong>on</strong>ometric approach and taken account <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> both selecti<strong>on</strong> bias and n<strong>on</strong>random<br />

program placement (Pitt and Khandker 1996&1998; Pitt et al. 1999; Coleman 1999 &<br />

2002; Khandker 2003; Khandker et al.1998; McKernan 2002; Morduch 1998). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

methodology was applied by Pitt and Khandker (1996&1998) to attempt to correct both<br />

selecti<strong>on</strong> bias and n<strong>on</strong>random program placement in group lending, is described as the<br />

below.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> authors used survey data <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grameen Bank and two other group lending<br />

programs in Bangladesh (the Bangladesh Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Development Studies (BIDS) and<br />

the World Bank). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y c<strong>on</strong>ducted a quasi-experimental household survey <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 87 villages<br />

in 29 thanas 14 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y sampled randomly for both members and n<strong>on</strong>members from villages<br />

that had a micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance program. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y also randomly chose households from villages<br />

without a program. In this case, credit program availability was applied as an identifying<br />

variable. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> authors, however, identified that systematic variati<strong>on</strong> will occur between<br />

the two kinds <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> villages because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the possibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> endogenous program placement.<br />

Thus, village fixed effects estimati<strong>on</strong> was applied to c<strong>on</strong>trol for unobserved variati<strong>on</strong><br />

between villages. Nevertheless, households living in program villages, which are<br />

exogenously excluded from the program by program rules which restrict participati<strong>on</strong> for<br />

household with more than 0.5 acres <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> land were principally excluded from membership<br />

14 A thana is the administrative center for numerous villages.<br />

28


c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> by any <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the three programs, that were sampled for this survey. This might<br />

have resulted from the possibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> collinearity between the village-specific dummy<br />

variables, identifying fixed effect, and the availability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the program. Many impact<br />

studies then applied a similar methodology. As can be seen from the studies by Pitt et al.<br />

(1999); Khandker (2003); Khandker et al.(1998); McKernan (2002); and Morduch (1998).<br />

But, Khandker (2003) did some further interesting work <strong>on</strong> the data set. He used the same<br />

data set as Pitt and Khandker (1996) and, then did a follow up survey <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the same<br />

households in 1998/99 to come with panel data. However, according to Coleman claimed<br />

to the eligibility criteria for membership c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>:<br />

Most group lending programs…do not impose such eligibility criteria. Rather,<br />

they attempt to attract the relatively poor and dissuade the relatively rich from<br />

participating by the small size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loans, the high frequency <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> meetings, and the<br />

stigma <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> bel<strong>on</strong>ging to a poor pers<strong>on</strong>’s credit program. Hence, the method <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Pitt<br />

and Khandker could not be implemented in most group lending programs.<br />

Moreover, even in the c<strong>on</strong>text <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the three Bangladesh programs they studied,<br />

their survey found that some 18-34% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> program participants in fact had wealth<br />

that should have excluded them from participating. Hence, the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this<br />

eligibility criteri<strong>on</strong> as a key exclusi<strong>on</strong> restricti<strong>on</strong> may not be appropriate<br />

(Coleman, 1999:110). 15<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> methodology applied by Coleman (1999) did not require the existence and<br />

enforcement <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> exogenously imposed membership criteria to identify program impact. As<br />

part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> his study, a unique survey which allows for the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relatively straightforward<br />

estimati<strong>on</strong> techniques was applied for data collecti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>n, the survey was d<strong>on</strong>e four<br />

15 Morduch’s study in 1998 (cited in Coleman 1999: 110) found that in program village, Pitt and Khandker<br />

marked “eligible” for households’ participati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the microcredit program as any households in program<br />

village, c<strong>on</strong>sisting households that should have been excluded principally. On the other hand, they follow<br />

exactly the rule <strong>on</strong> the eligibility criteria for marking household as eligible or not eligible in n<strong>on</strong>-program<br />

village. Thus, both “treatment” group and “c<strong>on</strong>trol” group was not c<strong>on</strong>formed each other, and it led to<br />

overestimated results <strong>on</strong> program impact.<br />

29


times over the course <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a year, during 1995-1996, for both members and n<strong>on</strong>members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

the village bank in 14 villages in Northeast Thailand. Six <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> those villages were identified<br />

as “c<strong>on</strong>trol” villages that were recognized to receive NGO support for village bank within<br />

<strong>on</strong>e year after the identificati<strong>on</strong>. It means that there was self-selecti<strong>on</strong> for villagers in six<br />

c<strong>on</strong>trol villages as participants had already decided whether or not they want to be<br />

membership <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the village bank. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rest <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> eight villages were “treatment” villages <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

which seven villages had a village bank for two to four years and <strong>on</strong>e village started its<br />

village bank suddenly after the first survey. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> comparis<strong>on</strong> between the “old” village<br />

bank members in the eight treatment villages and the “new” village bank members in the<br />

six “c<strong>on</strong>trol” villages could be undertaken. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the author identified precise<br />

impact estimator as a variati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the length <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> time for the program availability in the<br />

treatment villages. When n<strong>on</strong>members in all villages were included in the sample, this<br />

allows for the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> village fixed effect estimati<strong>on</strong> to c<strong>on</strong>trol the possibility that the order<br />

in which these 14 villages received program support is endogenous.<br />

Based <strong>on</strong> empirical evidence, most studies showed positive impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance <strong>on</strong> different dimensi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> outcomes at different levels, even though they<br />

applied various methodologies. Until now, no study <strong>on</strong> impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance in Laos<br />

has corrected the selecti<strong>on</strong> bias and endogenous program placement. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, this study<br />

will try to take into account that bias and the author will apply method used by Coleman<br />

(1999) to evaluate the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a village savings group in a semi-urban area <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos.<br />

30


CHAPTER 4<br />

ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK<br />

This paper will to examine the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance program by applying two<br />

sets <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> indicators – ec<strong>on</strong>omic and social indicators. To test the hypothesis that members<br />

with a l<strong>on</strong>g-term participati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the savings group may have better quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> life in<br />

terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> wealth, income and expenses, the theoretical framework, model specificati<strong>on</strong><br />

and methodology will be discussed in this chapter.<br />

4.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>oretical Framework<br />

In ec<strong>on</strong>omic perspectives, c<strong>on</strong>sumer theory is used to identify the c<strong>on</strong>sequences<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sumer behavior by maximizing c<strong>on</strong>sumer utility. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, <strong>on</strong> the basis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sumer theory, the impacts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance program can be illustrated<br />

by using the c<strong>on</strong>cept <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> utility maximizati<strong>on</strong>. To evaluate the effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> group-based<br />

credit program participati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> household behavior and intra-household resource<br />

allocati<strong>on</strong>, it will c<strong>on</strong>sider a simple model that generates an efficiency argument for<br />

targeted credit for the rural poor. This paper will follow the framework that was<br />

developed and used by Pitt and Khandker (1996).<br />

Assume that households <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> size n comprise two working age adults (the male<br />

head and his wife) plus n-2 dependents. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> households maximize a lifetime utility<br />

functi<strong>on</strong> which c<strong>on</strong>tains time-specific utility functi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the form:<br />

31


Where:<br />

U t = U ( n,<br />

Qi<br />

, H i , li<br />

)<br />

(1)<br />

Qi: a set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> market goods c<strong>on</strong>sumed by household member i,<br />

Hi: a set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>-market household-produced goods allocated to member i,<br />

li : leisure time c<strong>on</strong>sumed by household member i.<br />

To generalize (1), each <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the two adult household members, denoted by f and m, needs to<br />

maximizes his (if m) or her (if f) own utility uit,<br />

u it = ui<br />

( n,<br />

Qi<br />

, H i , li<br />

) , i = f,m (2)<br />

Where household social welfare is some functi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the individual utility<br />

functi<strong>on</strong>s U it = U ( u ft , umt<br />

) , it can be represented as<br />

U = u + ( 1−<br />

λ)<br />

u , 0 ≤ λ ≤ 1 (3)<br />

it<br />

λ ft<br />

mt<br />

In this, λ is the weight given to women’s preferences in the social welfare functi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

household. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> parameter λ can be thought to represent the bargaining power <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female<br />

household members relative to males in determining the intra-household allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

resources. When λ =0, female preferences are given no weight and the household’s social<br />

welfare functi<strong>on</strong> is identical to that <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the males. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> household-produced goods H<br />

include “household care” activities such as preparati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> food, childcare, and the<br />

gathering <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fuel.<br />

32


where,<br />

H mh fh<br />

= H ( L , L , G,<br />

F)<br />

(4)<br />

L mh : time devoted to the producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> H by males,<br />

L fh : time devoted to the producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> H by females,<br />

G : a vector <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> market goods used as inputs in the producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> H<br />

F : a vector <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> technology parameters that affect efficiency in H good producti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Due to socio-cultural factors, relatively few poor women work in the wage labor<br />

market. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> reservati<strong>on</strong> wage for market work is, therefore, relatively high. In additi<strong>on</strong> to<br />

this preference effect <strong>on</strong> female wage employment, workers typically must commit to a<br />

full day’s employment even in the spot labor market. If men’s time (or that <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> other<br />

household members) is a poor substitute for women’s time, and if important H-good<br />

outputs, such as child care and food preparati<strong>on</strong>, must be “produced” daily (cannot be<br />

stored), then working a full day may entail foregoing the producti<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

highly valued H goods. Thus, the n<strong>on</strong>-storability and time-intensity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

household goods H, the indivisibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> time allocati<strong>on</strong> in the wage labor market, and<br />

high reservati<strong>on</strong> wages due to cultural impediments to wage employment outside the<br />

home all result in most women being engaged in the producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household goods H in<br />

every period to the exclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> employment in market activities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se effects are<br />

magnified if λ is small and male preferences tend to favor certain kinds <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> H-goods<br />

produced <strong>on</strong> women's time.<br />

However, there are also ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities that produce goods to sell in the<br />

market that is not culturally frowned up<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se activities produce what we refer to as<br />

Z-goods. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se activities permit part-day labor and do not require that producti<strong>on</strong> occur<br />

33


away from the home. For many Z-goods a minimum level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> capital is necessary, even<br />

though many <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these producti<strong>on</strong> activities can be operated at low levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> capital<br />

intensity. This minimum is <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ten the result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the indivisibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> capital items. For<br />

example, dairy farming requires no less than <strong>on</strong>e cow, and hand-powered looms have a<br />

minimum size. For other activities, such as paddy husking, where the indivisibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

physical capital is not an issue, transacti<strong>on</strong> costs (or the high costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> informati<strong>on</strong>) take<br />

the place <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the minimal level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> operati<strong>on</strong>s. In many societies these indivisibilities may<br />

be inc<strong>on</strong>sequential, but am<strong>on</strong>g the rural poor <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> many developing countries, including<br />

Laos, household income and wealth is so low that the costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> initiating producti<strong>on</strong> at<br />

minimal ec<strong>on</strong>omic levels are quite high. Poverty alleviati<strong>on</strong> programs, such as the Rural<br />

Works Programs, which target households by drawing them into (in-kind) wage labor,<br />

have a comparatively small direct effect <strong>on</strong> the time allocati<strong>on</strong> and productivity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

women. In additi<strong>on</strong>, transportati<strong>on</strong> and other transacti<strong>on</strong> costs in labor markets may be so<br />

high as to make part-day labor un-remunerative. Formally, we represent the producti<strong>on</strong><br />

functi<strong>on</strong> for the Z-goods as:<br />

Where<br />

Z mz fz<br />

= Z(<br />

K,<br />

L , L , A,<br />

J )<br />

(5)<br />

L mz : labor time <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> head devoted to the producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Z,<br />

L fz : labor time <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> wife devoted to the producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Z,<br />

K : capital in Z producti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

A : a vector <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> variable inputs<br />

34


J: a vector <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> technology parameters that affect efficiency in Z-good producti<strong>on</strong><br />

(informati<strong>on</strong>).<br />

Positive producti<strong>on</strong> requires a minimal level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> capital K, Kmin. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> producti<strong>on</strong><br />

functi<strong>on</strong> (5) can be operated at a n<strong>on</strong>-zero level when Lmz or L fz are zero, but not when<br />

both are zero. For example, although at least <strong>on</strong>e cow is required in the producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

milk, any pers<strong>on</strong>’s labor can be used to obtain the milk. In other examples, Kmin may<br />

stand for the minimum informati<strong>on</strong> which is required to produce and market home<br />

producti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

<strong>Household</strong>s maximize lifetime utility subject to a budget c<strong>on</strong>straint that requires<br />

that the present discounted value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> expenditure <strong>on</strong> goods and leisure equal the present<br />

value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all wealth, defined as assets plus the discounted present value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the time<br />

endowments, and the two producti<strong>on</strong> functi<strong>on</strong> equati<strong>on</strong>s (4) and (5). <strong>Household</strong> ability to<br />

borrow has significant influence <strong>on</strong> the time path <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>. <strong>Household</strong>s<br />

having very low levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> initial assets as collateral may not be able to borrow to achieve<br />

the minimum capital requirements necessary to operate the Z-good activity. At very low<br />

levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income and c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>, reducing current c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> to accumulate assets<br />

for this purpose may not be optimal because it may seriously threaten health, producti<strong>on</strong><br />

efficiency, and life expectancy, as shown in Gersovitz (1983). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, for many<br />

households, the Z-good activity is never carried out (and Lfz = 0) and women who do not<br />

work in the wage labor market devote all their time to producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the n<strong>on</strong>-market good<br />

H and to leisure.<br />

35


4.2 Model Specificati<strong>on</strong> and Methodology<br />

4.2.1 Model Specificati<strong>on</strong><br />

From the model menti<strong>on</strong>ed above, the reduced-form determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> credit<br />

program participati<strong>on</strong> include:<br />

• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> prices <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> market time,<br />

• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the purchased market good Q,<br />

• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> prices <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the market inputs into H-good producti<strong>on</strong> including the cost<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> averting a birth and other determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fertility,<br />

• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> prices <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> variable inputs into Z-good producti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the capital good,<br />

• Age and educati<strong>on</strong> levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the borrower and spouse,<br />

• Access to transfers from n<strong>on</strong>-resident relatives and,<br />

• Village-level characteristics (V).<br />

Whether or not poor households, especially the women, are credit-c<strong>on</strong>strained is a<br />

complex issue. Rashid and Townsend (1994) c<strong>on</strong>cluded a detailed study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this issue in<br />

the c<strong>on</strong>text <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> targeted group-based lending. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y recommend that inefficient<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> and producti<strong>on</strong> outcomes may be a result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> risk, private informati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

communicati<strong>on</strong>s and enforcement difficulties. Significant evidence shows that collateral<br />

and educati<strong>on</strong>, the health risks and intermittency <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> employment associated with<br />

childbirth, and cultural barriers result in the limitati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> women participati<strong>on</strong> in the<br />

formal credit market. Rashid and Townsend note that the evidence does not in itself<br />

imply that outcomes are inefficient if, for example, women have access to other sources<br />

36


<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> finance such as transfers, or if male household members obtain funds for female<br />

household members.<br />

A primary focus <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this paper is to estimate the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> credit programs <strong>on</strong><br />

various household outcomes such as household c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>, household income, and<br />

household asset. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> author proposes to estimate the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al demand equati<strong>on</strong> for<br />

each outcome to be investigated, c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ed <strong>on</strong> the household’s program participati<strong>on</strong> as<br />

measured by the quantity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> credit borrowed. As noted earlier, the methodology adopted<br />

is that developed by Pitt and Khandker (1996). C<strong>on</strong>sider the reduced form equati<strong>on</strong> (6)<br />

for the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> participati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the credit programs by household i in village j ( C ij ),<br />

where level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> participati<strong>on</strong> will be taken to be the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> program credit<br />

where<br />

C = X β + V γ + Z π + ε<br />

(6)<br />

ij<br />

ij<br />

c<br />

j<br />

c<br />

Xij : a vector <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household characteristics (e.g., age and educati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household head),<br />

Vj: a vector <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> village characteristics (e.g. prices and community infrastructure),<br />

Zij : a set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household or village characteristics distinct from the X’s and V’s in that they<br />

affect Cij but not other household behaviors c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>on</strong> Cij (see below),<br />

β c , γ c , and π are unknown parameters,<br />

c<br />

ε ij : a random error having three comp<strong>on</strong>ents<br />

ε = μ + η + e<br />

(7)<br />

c<br />

ij<br />

j<br />

ij<br />

c<br />

ij<br />

ij<br />

37<br />

c<br />

ij


where<br />

μ : an unobserved village-specific effect,<br />

j<br />

η ij : an unobserved household-specific effect,<br />

c<br />

e ij : a n<strong>on</strong>-systematic error uncorrelated with the other error comp<strong>on</strong>ents or the regressors.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al demand for household outcome Yij c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>on</strong> the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> program<br />

participati<strong>on</strong> Cij is<br />

Y = X β + V γ + C δ + ε (8)<br />

ij<br />

ij<br />

y<br />

y<br />

where β y , γ y and δ are unknown parameters and ε ij is comprised <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

y<br />

ij<br />

j<br />

j<br />

y<br />

j<br />

y<br />

ε = ( αμ + μ ) + ( θη + η ) + e (9)<br />

where α and θ are parameters (corresp<strong>on</strong>ding to correlati<strong>on</strong> coefficients), y<br />

μ j and<br />

are additi<strong>on</strong>al village and household-specific errors uncorrelated with μ j and η ij ,<br />

ij<br />

respectively, and y<br />

e ij is a n<strong>on</strong>-systematic error uncorrelated with other error comp<strong>on</strong>ents<br />

y c<br />

or with the regressors. If α ≠0 or θ ≠0 the errors ε ij and ε ij are correlated. Ec<strong>on</strong>ometric<br />

estimati<strong>on</strong> that does not take this correlati<strong>on</strong> into account will yield biased estimates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

the parameters <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> equati<strong>on</strong> (8) due to the endogeneity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> credit program participati<strong>on</strong> Cij.<br />

4.2.2 Methodology<br />

ij<br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>ometric estimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this equati<strong>on</strong> (8) will yield biased parameter estimates<br />

y c<br />

if ε ij and ε ij are correlated and this correlati<strong>on</strong> is not taken into account. According to<br />

38<br />

y<br />

ij<br />

y<br />

ij<br />

y<br />

ij<br />

y<br />

η ij


Coleman (1999), two different sources which lead to such correlati<strong>on</strong> are (1) self-<br />

selecti<strong>on</strong> into the savings group and (2) n<strong>on</strong>random program placement. He illustrated<br />

sources <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> such correlati<strong>on</strong> that for the first source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> correlati<strong>on</strong>, by c<strong>on</strong>sidering a sample<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> households drawn <strong>on</strong>ly from with villages with a savings group 16 , some households<br />

will have selected to be savings group members, and others will have not selected to be<br />

y c<br />

members. ε ij and ε ij will almost definitely be correlated in this sample. For example, if<br />

there are many entrepreneurial households joining savings group, then unmeasured<br />

“entrepreneurship” would affect both the decisi<strong>on</strong> to become a member and impact<br />

y c<br />

measures such as income and assets. In c<strong>on</strong>trast, if ε ij and ε ij were negatively correlated,<br />

estimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group impact would be biased downward. For example, the<br />

relatively poor may join the savings group more than the rich who might feel stigmatized<br />

in a group for poor people.<br />

Coleman also dem<strong>on</strong>strated the sec<strong>on</strong>d source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> correlati<strong>on</strong> as follows:<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sider another comm<strong>on</strong>ly used sample, which includes households <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> village<br />

bank members from some villages and randomly selected households from<br />

villages without a village bank…Now it is possible for ε ij and μ ij to be<br />

correlated across villages if village bank placement is not random. For example, if<br />

some village are viewed as more entrepreneurial or better organized, have more<br />

dynamic leaders and such leadership spills over to effect others’ behavior in the<br />

village, or are simply poorer (e.g., living in flood-pr<strong>on</strong>e or drought-pr<strong>on</strong>e areas),<br />

16 In original paper <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Coleman (1999) used word <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> “village bank” but hence use word “savings group” to<br />

c<strong>on</strong>form to this study. Actually, village bank in Coleman’s case and savings group in this study are quite<br />

similar c<strong>on</strong>cept because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> they both are applied from village bank model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Foundati<strong>on</strong> for<br />

Internati<strong>on</strong>al Community Assistance (FINCA) but the village bank is much more dependent <strong>on</strong> external<br />

fund than internal fund which c<strong>on</strong>trast to the savings group. Please see Appendix B secti<strong>on</strong> 1.2.1 for point<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> view <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group and secti<strong>on</strong> 2.2.1 for its source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fund.<br />

39


and if NGOs use such criteria to determine village bank placement, then ε ij and<br />

μ ij will be correlated (Coleman, 1999: 113) 17 .<br />

To deal with the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> correlati<strong>on</strong> between y<br />

ε ij and<br />

40<br />

c<br />

ε ij<br />

18 , therefore, the author<br />

will follow the method <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Coleman (1999) 19 to measure the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong><br />

the household outcomes. As menti<strong>on</strong>ed in secti<strong>on</strong> 3.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> chapter 3, Coleman (1999)<br />

c<strong>on</strong>ducted a unique survey which permits the estimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an alternative, simpler<br />

specificati<strong>on</strong> allowing for the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relatively straightforward ec<strong>on</strong>ometric techniques to<br />

measures program impact.<br />

By applying Coleman’s method, the author c<strong>on</strong>ducted a survey <strong>on</strong> 251 households<br />

in six villages in semi-urban area <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos (Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g district). Of these, three villages<br />

had savings groups operating for more than a year, and are called “old” savings groups.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> remaining three villages had also started operating savings groups that were in<br />

existence for less than a year. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are called “new” savings groups (see table 5.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

next chapter). Both old and new savings groups cannot be identified as “treatment”<br />

villages and “c<strong>on</strong>trol” villages as the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the village banks in Northeast Thailand d<strong>on</strong>e<br />

by Coleman (1999). This is a result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> slight difference in the way funds are managed.<br />

Unlike the village banks in Coleman’s case, savings groups in this case study are much<br />

more dependent <strong>on</strong> internal funds than external funds (NGOs’support) (see more<br />

17<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> words <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> “village bank” and the symbols <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> “ ε ij ” and “ μ ij ” used in the paper <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Coleman (1999)<br />

c<br />

y<br />

are equivalent to the words <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> “savings group” and symbols <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> “ ε ij ” and “ ε ij ” used in this study<br />

respectively.<br />

18<br />

To cope with such correlati<strong>on</strong>, M<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fitt (1991) suggests three standard procedures: using instrumental<br />

variables, using panel data, and assuming an error distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the outcome variable without treatment.<br />

For more explanati<strong>on</strong> was menti<strong>on</strong>ed in the paper <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> M<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fitt (1991: 295-305).<br />

19<br />

Aghi<strong>on</strong> and Morduch (2005) also suggested that the method <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Coleman (1999) is <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the approaches<br />

for impact evaluati<strong>on</strong> to address selecti<strong>on</strong> bias.


explanati<strong>on</strong> in Appendix B under secti<strong>on</strong> 2.2.1). It means that some savings group<br />

members can obtain a credit in short time (two or three days) after the establishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

savings group by depending <strong>on</strong> internal fund (savings from members). Or some new<br />

savings group members can access a loan quickly after self-selecting to become a<br />

member 20 . However, there were many villagers who had already self-selected to become<br />

members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings groups, but had not obtained any credit from savings groups yet.<br />

This was the case in both old and new savings groups, particularly am<strong>on</strong>g old members 21<br />

in the old savings groups who were with the savings group for more than a year. This<br />

may be result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> demand for credit because they may have enough funds to<br />

run their activities or to smooth their c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir motivati<strong>on</strong> for participating in<br />

the savings group may have been to benefit from the yearly dividends they could expect<br />

from their m<strong>on</strong>thly deposit with the savings groups.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> classificati<strong>on</strong> above allows the author to set a “treatment” group in which<br />

savings group members have gained benefit from joining the savings group by either<br />

obtaining a credit or receiving a dividend. Similarly, a “c<strong>on</strong>trol” group in which savings<br />

group members have not benefited from the savings groups can be identified. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>trol<br />

group <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group households would presumably, <strong>on</strong> average, share the same<br />

unobservable characteristics (such as entrepreneurship, gender attitude, etc.) as the<br />

treatment group <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group members (Coleman, 1999 and Mosley, 1997). In both<br />

20 It is normally <strong>on</strong>e or two day(s) to get a loan after becoming a member <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group if the savings<br />

group has enough funds and the member meet the requirements for borrowing.<br />

21 13.98 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> member sample (n=93) in old savings groups has never borrowed from the savings<br />

groups since they have been a savings group member. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir membership ages varied from 11.5 m<strong>on</strong>ths to<br />

35.5 m<strong>on</strong>ths.<br />

41


old and new villages, both members and n<strong>on</strong>members were surveyed. With this survey<br />

design, equati<strong>on</strong> (8) can be replaced by a single impact equati<strong>on</strong> 22 as follows:<br />

Where<br />

Y = X α + V β + M γ + T δ + υ<br />

(10)<br />

ij<br />

ij<br />

Yij ,Vj , and Xij are defined as before<br />

j<br />

ij<br />

ij<br />

Mij : a membership dummy variable equal to 1 if household ij self-selects into the<br />

savings group, and 0 otherwise.<br />

Tij : a dummy variable equal to 1 if a self-selected member has already had gained<br />

benefit from savings groups 23 , and 0 otherwise.<br />

δ : measures the average impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group <strong>on</strong> Yij.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> membership dummy variable Mij can be thought <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> as a proxy for the<br />

unobservable characteristics that lead households to self-select into the savings group.<br />

For example, it captures the unobserved variables that led to the correlati<strong>on</strong> across<br />

households between y<br />

ε ij and<br />

42<br />

ij<br />

c<br />

ε ij . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> variable Tij which measures availability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

savings group to members who have self-selected is exogenous to the household. This is<br />

unlike the amount borrowed (which may not be exogenous with respect to the village, as<br />

discussed below).<br />

According to Coleman’s (1999) specificati<strong>on</strong>, the variable Mij which captures<br />

unobservable household characteristics, can eliminate the correlati<strong>on</strong> between Tij and y<br />

ε ij<br />

22 This equati<strong>on</strong> was adopted from the study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Coleman (1999).<br />

23 This is slightly different from Coleman’s case (1999) which he used access to program credit as<br />

distinguish between c<strong>on</strong>trol and treatment village but this study, the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a gain from participati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

savings group by either obtaining a credit or receiving a dividend is to be the proxy for distinguishing<br />

between c<strong>on</strong>trol and treatment group.


due to self-selecti<strong>on</strong> at the household level. In additi<strong>on</strong>, if the order in which villages<br />

have savings group program placement is random with respect to unobserved village<br />

characteristics, then efficient and unbiased estimates can be obtained with Vj as a vector<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> specific village characteristic affecting Yij. However, if the order is not random with<br />

respect to unobservable village characteristics, then using specific village characteristics<br />

as regressors will lead to a biased estimate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> impact. This is a difference <strong>on</strong> the sec<strong>on</strong>d<br />

source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> bias discussed above. While in this study does not c<strong>on</strong>trol villages and<br />

treatment villages, the problem <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>-random program placement is resolved by the<br />

author dividing the six villages which have own savings groups in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> different<br />

times <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> establishment (that is, three old and three new savings groups). However, the<br />

order in which villages had program support to establish a savings group may not be<br />

random. For example, if the most dynamic villages established a savings group with the<br />

y<br />

program support before less dynamic villages, then Tij and ε ij will be positively<br />

correlated and δ will be biased. One method to eliminate this bias is through village<br />

fixed effects estimati<strong>on</strong> (Coleman, 1999). If the order <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group placement is<br />

random 24 , however, then village fixed effects estimati<strong>on</strong> is still unbiased, but less<br />

efficient than using specific village characteristics as regressors.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> empirical model in (10) can be improved up<strong>on</strong> by recognizing that some<br />

treatment members have received benefit from joining savings groups l<strong>on</strong>ger than others.<br />

In the six villages, the age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group differed from <strong>on</strong>e m<strong>on</strong>th to three years.<br />

24 Un<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ficial informati<strong>on</strong> obtained from the Project’s staff and the District Lao Women’s Uni<strong>on</strong> at<br />

Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g city noted that the villages which have three old savings groups were target villages. Before the<br />

establishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings groups in those villages, the project prop<strong>on</strong>ents came to the villages to discuss the<br />

possibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group establishment with local authorities <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> those villages. By c<strong>on</strong>trast, the local<br />

authorities in the villages with the “new” savings groups, themselves had approached the project<br />

prop<strong>on</strong>ents and requested them to establish a micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance program in their villages.<br />

43


Of these six villages, there were members who classified to the treatment group and have<br />

their membership ages varied as the age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group. Giving that the cumulative<br />

amount that a member can borrow grows over the life <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group, and that a<br />

member can receive a dividend every twelve m<strong>on</strong>ths, <strong>on</strong>e would expect to see greater<br />

impact in villages with older savings group. Hence the empirical model estimated, which<br />

is based <strong>on</strong> the <strong>on</strong>e used by the Coleman (1999), is as follows:<br />

Y = X α + V β + M γ + MAMT δ + μ<br />

(11)<br />

ij<br />

ij<br />

j<br />

ij<br />

44<br />

ij<br />

Where μij is error representing unmeasured household and village characteristics<br />

that determine outcomes; the treatment dummy variable Tij is replaced by MAMTij, the<br />

numbers <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>ths the savings group has been operating in the village. In other word,<br />

MAMTij can be thought <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> as the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>ths participants have gained benefits<br />

from participati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings groups. MAMTij is zero for members in c<strong>on</strong>trol group and<br />

for n<strong>on</strong>members in the six villages. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, MAMTij is a more precise measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

program availability than Tij. Now, δ measures the impact per m<strong>on</strong>th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> program<br />

availability. Like the equati<strong>on</strong> (10), if the order <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> program placement is random with<br />

respect to unobservable village characteristics, then efficient and unbiased estimates can<br />

be obtained with Vj as a vector <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> specific village characteristics. If program placement,<br />

however, is not random with respect to unobservable village characteristics, then MAMTij<br />

and<br />

y<br />

ε ij can be eliminated with village fixed effects. This specificati<strong>on</strong> (11) is<br />

c<strong>on</strong>siderably easier to estimate (if Yij is uncensored, then OLS is appropriate), according<br />

to Coleman (1999).<br />

ij


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> regressi<strong>on</strong> results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the equati<strong>on</strong> (11) by employing Coleman’s (1999)<br />

methodology, to evaluate the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household outcomes will be<br />

presented in chapter 6. Before moving to that, survey method and data will be described<br />

in the next chapter.<br />

45


CHAPTER 5<br />

SURVEY DESIGN<br />

Many micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs provide financial services to the poor and lower<br />

income people in urban and semi-urban areas <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Women and Community’s<br />

Empowering Project (WCEP) is <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the many programs which launched micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance<br />

programs in semi-urban areas <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> project provides micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance through a<br />

“savings group” in three districts in Vientiane, the capital <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos. One <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these three<br />

cities was selected for this case study (see Appendix B for the overview <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the project and<br />

this case study). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> reas<strong>on</strong> this case study was c<strong>on</strong>ducted in the Vientiane area is due to<br />

the fact that most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings groups operate in and around the capital. It can be seen that<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 357 savings groups throughout the country that are being m<strong>on</strong>itored by seven<br />

agencies 25 , a significant number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings groups are running in Vientiane Capital City.<br />

Most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the groups in Vientiane are operating with the technical support <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> two main<br />

bilateral projects – “Small and Rural Development Project for Women” and “Capacity<br />

Building Project for Women and Community,” – between the Central Lao Women’s<br />

Uni<strong>on</strong>, the Foundati<strong>on</strong> for Integrated Agricultural Management (FIAM) and Community<br />

Organizati<strong>on</strong>s Development Institute: Thailand (CODI) (the postal survey c<strong>on</strong>ducted by<br />

the Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance Capacity Building and Research Project (2003), cited in Chaleunsinh,<br />

25 Seven agencies c<strong>on</strong>sist <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> District Lao Women’s Uni<strong>on</strong>, District Lao Youth’s Uni<strong>on</strong>, District Planning<br />

Office, District Social <strong>Welfare</strong> Office, District Finance Office, District Agriculture and Forestry Office and<br />

branches <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Agriculture Promoti<strong>on</strong> Bank (Chaleunsinh, 2004).<br />

46


2004:7). This secti<strong>on</strong> discusses how the survey c<strong>on</strong>ducted and provides a descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

the data used for this study.<br />

5.1 Survey design 26<br />

In September 2005, a survey was c<strong>on</strong>ducted <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 251 households in six villages in<br />

the Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g district which have their own savings group. At the time <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> survey, three<br />

villages had just established “new” savings groups. Two <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these were three m<strong>on</strong>ths old,<br />

<strong>on</strong>e was existent for just <strong>on</strong>e m<strong>on</strong>th (see table 5.1). Other three villages had “old” savings<br />

groups ranging in existence from just over <strong>on</strong>e year to almost three years. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se were<br />

selected from the list <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings groups provided by the project administers <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> projects.<br />

Chose to the three “new” savings groups selected for this study under distance c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

It means that the three old savings groups were not far from the three new savings groups<br />

– under 15 Kilometer. Both members and n<strong>on</strong>members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the village savings group were<br />

encouraged to interview. <strong>Household</strong>s which had a least <strong>on</strong>e pers<strong>on</strong> as a member <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a<br />

savings group were selected for interview and households which has no <strong>on</strong>e joining the<br />

savings group were also chosen for interview as shown in table 5.1. A random sampling<br />

method was not employed because a quasi-census survey <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> member and n<strong>on</strong>member<br />

households was c<strong>on</strong>ducted. Both old and new savings groups included two kinds <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

members:<br />

26 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> method for survey design was the <strong>on</strong>e used by Coleman (1999) for c<strong>on</strong>ducting survey in 14 village<br />

banks in Northeast Thailand as menti<strong>on</strong>ed in secti<strong>on</strong> 3.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Chapter 3. However, the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings groups<br />

Laos are mostly depended <strong>on</strong> internal fund which mobilized m<strong>on</strong>ey from member deposit to lend out to<br />

their members (see more explanati<strong>on</strong> in Appendix B under secti<strong>on</strong> 2.2.1). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, hence could not<br />

identified the new village savings groups to be as “C<strong>on</strong>trol Villages” and the old village savings groups as<br />

“Treatment Villages”; however, there are “C<strong>on</strong>trol” group and “Treatment” group for both old and new<br />

village savings groups as identified in this secti<strong>on</strong>, which are quite different from the Coleman’s case.<br />

47


• Members who had gained some benefit from the savings groups by either<br />

obtaining a credit or receiving a dividend from the savings group since<br />

they had been members. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se members are classified as the Treatment<br />

group.<br />

• Members who were identified as C<strong>on</strong>trol group, are an inversi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

treatment group.<br />

Questi<strong>on</strong>naires were d<strong>on</strong>e in three sets. One was for households in the six villages, which<br />

were interviewed for both members and n<strong>on</strong>members. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> questi<strong>on</strong>naire c<strong>on</strong>ducted for<br />

this study is a replicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Hulme and Mosley (1996). A similar study was c<strong>on</strong>ducted<br />

for Saithani case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance by Sichath<strong>on</strong>gthip (2004) and it was also<br />

reproduced by Mosley (2001) in the study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance and poverty in Bolivia.<br />

However, the questi<strong>on</strong>naire was slightly modified in some parts to be more suitable and<br />

relevant for the purposes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this study. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> household questi<strong>on</strong>naire c<strong>on</strong>tained data <strong>on</strong><br />

household characteristics, assets, income, expenditure, deposits and borrowing. Some<br />

data <strong>on</strong> household assets, income, expenditure were asked for the current period (at<br />

survey date <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> September 2005) as well as recall period (5 years before c<strong>on</strong>ducting the<br />

survey). In each household which have a member <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group, an adult or head <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

household, who knows almost everything about the household finances, was invited for<br />

interview 27 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> same method was d<strong>on</strong>e for households which had no members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

savings group.<br />

27 Most interviewees were women (wives) because, in Lao custom, most wives know most about income<br />

and expenses <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their household. As Sheck-Sandbergen and Choulamany-Khampoui (1995: 91) noted about<br />

women in Laos, “Women are generally good at financial management and accounting because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their<br />

social and ec<strong>on</strong>omic experience in managing the household finances and the local ec<strong>on</strong>omy: they are the<br />

sellers, buyers, traders, middle-women and entrepreneurs” (quoted by Kunkel and Seibel 1997:116).<br />

48


Table 5.1: Sample size<br />

No. Savings groups<br />

Established<br />

date <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

savings<br />

group<br />

Number<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

household<br />

in village<br />

Number<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

household<br />

in savings<br />

group<br />

49<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

n<strong>on</strong>member<br />

household<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings<br />

group Sample size by:<br />

Member<br />

in<br />

treatment<br />

group<br />

Member in<br />

c<strong>on</strong>trol<br />

group<br />

Total<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

sample<br />

size<br />

N<strong>on</strong>member<br />

I. Old savings group in:<br />

1 Nakountay village 01-Oct-02 215 186 29 39 3 19 61<br />

2 Huannamyene village 12-Jun-03 353 217 136 34 1 13 48<br />

3 D<strong>on</strong>gluang village 01-Apr-04 184 75 a<br />

109 16 0 8 24<br />

Sub-total<br />

II. New savings group in:<br />

752 478 274 89 4 40 133<br />

4 Ph<strong>on</strong>ekeo village 15-Jun-05 95 80 15 8 19 6 33<br />

5 Ph<strong>on</strong>esavanh village 01-Jun-05 123 56 67 19 9 17 45<br />

6 Sisavard village 10-Aug-05 59 53 6 15 20 5 40<br />

Sub-total 277 189 88 42 48 28 118<br />

Grand total 1,029 667 362 131 52 68 251<br />

Note: a) this figure is assumed equal to the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> families in the savings group.<br />

Source: Author’s survey data, September 2005 and March 2006.


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d questi<strong>on</strong>naire was for collecting village informati<strong>on</strong> including<br />

characteristics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the villages such as the presence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> schools and prices <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods in each<br />

village. This interview was c<strong>on</strong>ducted with the head <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the village and members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

group committee at the village level.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> last questi<strong>on</strong>naire was for general informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> savings group. It included<br />

questi<strong>on</strong>s regarding the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the group members, sources <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> funds, group deposit<br />

balances, deposits and credit methods, and methodology for solving bad debts (in case).<br />

This interview was c<strong>on</strong>ducted in depth for the group committee at the village level.<br />

In September 2005, the household surveys were administered by third year<br />

students <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the faculty <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omics and business management from the Nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos, together with the author. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se students were trained <strong>on</strong> how to<br />

c<strong>on</strong>duct a survey before interviewing the villagers. During survey period, the author was<br />

the leader <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the team and supervised all the students to ensure that correct informati<strong>on</strong><br />

was obtained. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the author c<strong>on</strong>ducted the village surveys as well as in-depth<br />

interviews with the group committees. Finally, the author c<strong>on</strong>ducted a follow up survey<br />

in March 2006. This survey was targeted at collecting more data <strong>on</strong> village characteristics<br />

and additi<strong>on</strong>al data <strong>on</strong> deposits, credits and other areas which the previous surveys had<br />

not covered. Informati<strong>on</strong> for the last survey was mostly obtained from the group<br />

committee and gathered by in-depth interviews with the chief <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao Women Uni<strong>on</strong> at<br />

Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g district. In additi<strong>on</strong>, sec<strong>on</strong>dary data from project documents (summary report,<br />

progress report, savings group manual and other) were obtained from the project, Lao<br />

Women Uni<strong>on</strong> at Municipality level and group committee.<br />

50


5.2 Data descripti<strong>on</strong><br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> data used in this analysis is taken from the author’s survey in September 2005<br />

and March 2006 as described above. All variables used for this study were drawn from<br />

the studies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Coleman (1999 and 2002); Hulme and Mosley (1996); Pitt and Khandker<br />

(1996 and 1998); and from Annex 1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Gaile and Foster (1996). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> main dependent<br />

variables which represent proxies for the household’s outcomes are classified in three<br />

main parts: household m<strong>on</strong>thly expenditure, household yearly income and household<br />

assets. <strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly expenditure c<strong>on</strong>sists <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> two main categories: household<br />

m<strong>on</strong>thly food expenditure and household m<strong>on</strong>thly n<strong>on</strong>-food expenditure. <strong>Household</strong><br />

yearly income is classified to two main parts: household yearly self-employment income<br />

and household yearly n<strong>on</strong> self-employment income. <strong>Household</strong> assets comprise<br />

household owned land and house assets, and household owned n<strong>on</strong>-land and house assets.<br />

Independent variables are mainly characteristics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> households and villages but<br />

the variable <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> most interest for this study is the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>ths a pers<strong>on</strong> has been a<br />

member <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a savings group. <strong>Household</strong> characteristic variables are age, gender, educati<strong>on</strong><br />

level, household size, for example. Village characteristic variables c<strong>on</strong>sist <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> distance to<br />

market, price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods, having a school and being near a river, for example. More details<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> data descripti<strong>on</strong> are shown in the Appendix A: table 1-4.<br />

51


CHAPTER 6<br />

EMPIRICAL RESULTS<br />

This chapter presents and interprets the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> estimating a single impact<br />

equati<strong>on</strong> (11) for a wide variety <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household outcomes. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se outcomes include<br />

household house asset value 28 , household annual self employment income from livestock,<br />

household annual self employment income from agriculture, household m<strong>on</strong>thly rental<br />

expenditure, and household m<strong>on</strong>thly educati<strong>on</strong>al expenditure 29 . Before moving to those<br />

results, some particular innovati<strong>on</strong>s and specificati<strong>on</strong>s for estimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the equati<strong>on</strong> (11)<br />

will be briefly described below.<br />

As menti<strong>on</strong>ed in chapter 4, this study applies the analytical method used by<br />

Coleman (1999). Four innovati<strong>on</strong>s borrowed from his study have been incorporated in<br />

the equati<strong>on</strong> (11) for measuring the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group:<br />

1) It allows for use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> village fixed effects 30 ;<br />

2) It identifies a c<strong>on</strong>trol group <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> members who have not benefited from the<br />

savings groups and then surveys “treatment” members, “c<strong>on</strong>trol” members<br />

and n<strong>on</strong>members, thus allowing for the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a member dummy variable<br />

28<br />

This value stands for value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> house with land (not empty land or land for rice field and crop plant).<br />

Barnes (1996:4) noted that house asset is <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the physical assets representing for the wealth <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

household.<br />

29<br />

For other proxies representing for household outcomes as shown in Appendix A-table 1-4 are not<br />

reported in this paper. According to the ec<strong>on</strong>ometric exercise, those outcomes do not show significant<br />

correlati<strong>on</strong> with the regressor <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest (m<strong>on</strong>ths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group membership).<br />

30<br />

This was used by Pitt and Khandker (1996&1998); Pitt et al. (1999); Khandker et al. (1998); Mckernan<br />

(2002); Coleman (1999&2002).<br />

52


to be a proxy for unobservable differences between members and<br />

n<strong>on</strong>members;<br />

3) It uses the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> land owned by household five years before this survey<br />

was c<strong>on</strong>ducted to be a proxy for initial household wealth 31 ;<br />

4) It uses the length <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> time that the savings group has been in a village to<br />

obtain more precise impact measures.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, this study uses four specificati<strong>on</strong>s from Coleman (1999) to illustrate<br />

the importance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the four innovati<strong>on</strong>s to correct the bias resulting from self-selecti<strong>on</strong> and<br />

endogenous program placement. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> four specificati<strong>on</strong>s are described below:<br />

1) First is the “correct” specificati<strong>on</strong> which use village fixed effects and<br />

include a member dummy variable and variable for land value owned by<br />

the household five year before this survey. As menti<strong>on</strong>ed in chapter 4,<br />

fixed effects estimates will be c<strong>on</strong>sistent (and unbiased if the dependent<br />

variable is uncensored) but possibly inefficient.<br />

2) Sec<strong>on</strong>d is the specificati<strong>on</strong> which is identical to the first but this includes a<br />

vector <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> specific village characteristics 32 that <strong>on</strong>e might expect to<br />

influence the dependent variables. If the order <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> program placement is<br />

random, and the author was fortunate enough to choose all the relevant<br />

31 Proporti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> land value is 91.38 per cent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household wealth in this sample and land value is an<br />

excellent proxy for wealth which is similar to Coleman’s (1999) case. This land value comes from the<br />

value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> empty land or land for agriculture or any land which is not for house building. According to<br />

Coleman (1999), collecting data <strong>on</strong> land owned five years before the surveys is relatively easy. Because<br />

land transacti<strong>on</strong>s tend to be large and important for a household, yet relatively infrequent, households can<br />

easily recall land transacti<strong>on</strong>s made in the previous five years, and land owned five year earlier (and its<br />

value) can be deduced. Of course, collecting similar data <strong>on</strong> other assets is not feasible without surveying<br />

over several years.<br />

32 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se village characteristics include dummy variable for that village has either a pig p<strong>on</strong>d which has<br />

water throughout the year or be near river; dummy variable for that village has paved road or near main<br />

road (Km 13 road); dummy variable for that village has primary school grade5; a distance from village to<br />

main market; a price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> traditi<strong>on</strong>al chicken (Gailard) per Kg; and daily wage for c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

53


observable village characteristics, then the estimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>fixed effects<br />

(“village characteristics” or VC) model will be efficient and c<strong>on</strong>sistent<br />

(and unbiased if the dependent variable is uncensored). If the order <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

program placement is not random, or the author chose the wr<strong>on</strong>g village<br />

characteristics, then the estimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this model will be biased and<br />

inc<strong>on</strong>sistent.<br />

3) Third is “naive” estimates which ignore the first two innovati<strong>on</strong>s. For<br />

example, the naïve estimates use specific village characteristics rather than<br />

fixed effects, and they leave out the member dummy variable.<br />

4) Fourth is “super-naive” estimates which are identical to the third but also<br />

ignore the third innovati<strong>on</strong> by leaving out the variables for land value<br />

owned five years before the survey 33 .<br />

In this study, assuming that dependent variables (household outcomes) are<br />

uncensored, the method <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ordinary least squares (OLS) is applied for estimating the<br />

equati<strong>on</strong> (11). In additi<strong>on</strong>, the White test is applied to test for heteroskedasticity which<br />

lead to unbiased estimators <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> OLS. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>n, the generalized least squares estimati<strong>on</strong> (GLS)<br />

is used to correct heteroskedasticity, called weighted least squares (WLS) estimati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

(Wooldridge, 2003: 268-276).<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> regressi<strong>on</strong> result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the equati<strong>on</strong> (11) which covered all above methods will<br />

be discussed bellow under categories <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <strong>on</strong> household house assets, self-<br />

employment activities and educati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

33 According to Coleman (1999), the naïve models corresp<strong>on</strong>d to the models most comm<strong>on</strong>ly used to<br />

measure impact, which ignore selecti<strong>on</strong> bias, endogenous program placement, and prior wealth.<br />

54


6.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> household house asset<br />

To measure the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group participati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> household house assets,<br />

all four specificati<strong>on</strong>s, menti<strong>on</strong>ed above, were applied to the equati<strong>on</strong> (11). Four sets <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

regressi<strong>on</strong> results for impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household house asset value,<br />

corresp<strong>on</strong>ding to four specificati<strong>on</strong>s, are presented in Table 5 (Appendix A). Jointly<br />

significant test <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> explanatory variables shows str<strong>on</strong>gly significant evidence at the 1 per<br />

cent level for all four methods regressi<strong>on</strong>s. All four specificati<strong>on</strong> regressi<strong>on</strong>s show that<br />

the savings group has positive and significant impact <strong>on</strong> household asset value. It can be<br />

seen that both fixed effect estimati<strong>on</strong> and n<strong>on</strong>fixed effect estimati<strong>on</strong> dem<strong>on</strong>strate reliable<br />

explanatory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the m<strong>on</strong>thly savings group membership with large and significance at the<br />

5 per cent level (292,097; p = 0.0493) and at the 10 per cent level (292,097; p = 0.0522)<br />

respectively. In c<strong>on</strong>trast, the regressi<strong>on</strong> results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> both naïve and super-naïve models<br />

which ignore the first two and the first three innovati<strong>on</strong>s respectively, also show<br />

significant impact with large proporti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the m<strong>on</strong>th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group<br />

member at the 1 per cent level as (335,021; p = 0.0066) and (358,260; p = 0.0041)<br />

respectively. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se results are in c<strong>on</strong>trast with those <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Coleman (1999 &<br />

2002) that showed insignificant effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> village bank <strong>on</strong> house value.<br />

Table 5 (Appendix A) shows that the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the member dummy variable<br />

in the household house asset value is insignificant (1,481,225; p = 0.6816), indicating that<br />

unobservable differences between members and n<strong>on</strong>members (such as entrepreneurship,<br />

preferences, etc.) are <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> little c<strong>on</strong>sequence. This is c<strong>on</strong>sistent with the result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

coefficient <strong>on</strong> member dummy variable and the house value in the fixed effect model<br />

found by the Coleman (1999 & 2002). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, in the fixed effect model, there is no<br />

55


correlati<strong>on</strong> between the member dummy variable and the household house asset value.<br />

Hence, there is no correlati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> selecti<strong>on</strong> bias from unobservables.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, the coefficient <strong>on</strong> the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned land 5 years ago is<br />

positive but it is statistically insignificant at least at the 10 per cent level against a two-<br />

side alternative by employing the first three specificati<strong>on</strong>s. However, if we look at P-<br />

value level, the fixed effects and n<strong>on</strong>fixed effects estimati<strong>on</strong>s show those coefficients as<br />

(0.068769; p = 0.1683) and (0.068769; p = 0.1710) respectively, implying that those<br />

coefficients are acceptable at the 16.83 per cent and 17.1 per cent level. It means that the<br />

initial wealth <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household could slightly increase the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household house asset.<br />

Nevertheless, the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female-owned land value 5 years ago is positive and<br />

statistically significant at the 1 per cent level to women’s wealth in the study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Coleman<br />

(1999).<br />

One might expect the women who are the head <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a household to participate more<br />

actively in the savings group than women who are not the head <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household. However,<br />

the coefficient <strong>on</strong> this variable and the household house asset value in all four<br />

specificati<strong>on</strong>s regressi<strong>on</strong>s is insignificant at least 10 per cent level. This may be explained<br />

by the fact that 52 per cent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> women who are the household head are either single,<br />

widowed, divorced. This implies that there was no male adult in the households to help<br />

with any household activities, particularly ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities. According to Kunkel and<br />

Seibel (1997:106), in Lao Loum group 34 , there is a divisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> labor, but not fixed,<br />

34 As Kunkel and Seibel (1997:6) note, “<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ethnography <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos comprises the lowland Lao Loum who<br />

grow paddy in the river valleys al<strong>on</strong>g the Mek<strong>on</strong>g and its tributaries but also include the upland Tai Dam,<br />

who are n<strong>on</strong>-Buddhist; the upland Lao <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ung many <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> which practice slash-and-burn agriculture in the<br />

hills above the valleys and <strong>on</strong> the mountain slopes; and the mountain-top Lao Soung who have l<strong>on</strong>g<br />

resisted government efforts at resettlement and the substituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> new for old cash crops.” In this case<br />

study, all sample come from Lao Loum group.<br />

56


etween the two sexes in households for doing household work, agriculture work,<br />

livestock, collecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> forest products and handicrafts. Many <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> roles <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> women and men<br />

are overlap.<br />

However, women who do or run family activities, especially ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities,<br />

(or are entrepreneur) have positive significant increase <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household house asset value. It<br />

can be seen that the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> gender variable is positive and significant in relati<strong>on</strong> to<br />

household house asset value in all four estimati<strong>on</strong> models. For example, there is positive<br />

correlati<strong>on</strong> between gender variable and household house asset value (14,021,407; p =<br />

0.093), corresp<strong>on</strong>ding to the fixed effect estimati<strong>on</strong> model (see Appendix A: Table 5).<br />

Educati<strong>on</strong> level is highly significant in all four estimati<strong>on</strong> models at the 5 per cent<br />

level. For example, in case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fixed effect estimati<strong>on</strong> model, the coefficient <strong>on</strong> maximum<br />

educati<strong>on</strong> by individuals is large and significant (854,694; p = 0.0442). If educati<strong>on</strong>’s<br />

years can be c<strong>on</strong>sidered as a proxy for human capital, then this result likely stands for the<br />

complementarities <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> human capital and physical capital in producti<strong>on</strong> (Coleman,<br />

1999:120). Coleman (1999) also discovered the positively significant correlati<strong>on</strong> between<br />

educati<strong>on</strong> level for both females and males and women’s wealth but they were shown in<br />

case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the “super-naive” estimati<strong>on</strong> model <strong>on</strong>ly.<br />

Age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the individuals is totally positive significance at the 5 per cent level,<br />

corresp<strong>on</strong>ding to the four specificati<strong>on</strong> models. In case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fixed effect estimati<strong>on</strong><br />

model, for example, the coefficient <strong>on</strong> the age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals is largely significant<br />

(312,418; p = 0.023). It could be interpreted that the older <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the individuals in the<br />

households who participate in the savings group, the more significant is the increase in<br />

their household house asset value. This result was also found by Coleman (1999). He<br />

57


evealed that the coefficient <strong>on</strong> age-sex categories with women age 40 to 59 and women<br />

age 60 and over were positive and significant at the 5 per cent and 1 per cent levels<br />

respectively to women’s wealth. However, his result was shown by the super-naïve<br />

estimati<strong>on</strong> model <strong>on</strong>ly.<br />

People, who have run their business or family activities for a l<strong>on</strong>g time, have been<br />

increasing their household wealth. More experience in running the business or family<br />

activities, may lead to effectiveness and efficiency in producti<strong>on</strong> by the accumulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

knowledge and experience in that field. It can be seen that the coefficient <strong>on</strong> number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

m<strong>on</strong>ths doing business are significant at the 1 per cent level to household house asset<br />

value, corresp<strong>on</strong>ding to the four estimati<strong>on</strong> models (see Appendix A: Table 5).<br />

It is not surprising that the influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relatives in the village <strong>on</strong><br />

household house asset value is positive and significant at the 1 per cent level for the four<br />

estimati<strong>on</strong> models. For example, the coefficient <strong>on</strong> the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relatives in the village<br />

to the household house asset value is large and significant (1,552,376; p = 0.0001), in<br />

case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fixed effects estimati<strong>on</strong> model. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relatives represents village<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships that would help each other when facing serious situati<strong>on</strong>s including self-<br />

employment activities, or to share happiness am<strong>on</strong>g them.<br />

Having a chief <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a savings group committee or member <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the group committee<br />

in household has a large and statistically significant impact <strong>on</strong> household house asset<br />

value at the 1 per cent level for the four estimati<strong>on</strong> models. It is statistically significant<br />

(12,703,787; p = 0.0026) in case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fixed effect estimati<strong>on</strong> model, for example.<br />

Similarly, Coleman (1999) found large positive correlati<strong>on</strong> between the independent<br />

58


variable <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> having a village chief or assistant chief in the household and women’s wealth<br />

for the first three specificati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

One might expect that living in the village that has paved roads or been a near<br />

main road may improve household status more than living in the village does not have<br />

these advantages. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>fixed effects, naïve and super-naïve models were negative<br />

effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a variable for village characteristic – village has paved road or been near main<br />

road – <strong>on</strong> household house asset value with statistically significant level at 5 per cent as<br />

shown in Table 5 (Appendix A). This result is somewhat anomalous and difficult to<br />

explain. However, overall, the empirical results show that participati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group<br />

has been increasing household asset value by employing all four estimati<strong>on</strong> models.<br />

6.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> self-employment activities<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> self-employment activities are explained by three<br />

impact categories: household annual self employment income from livestock, household<br />

annual self employment income from agriculture, and household m<strong>on</strong>thly rental<br />

expenditure 35 .<br />

6.2.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g>s <strong>on</strong> household annual self employment income from livestock<br />

By regressing the equati<strong>on</strong> (11) with the four estimati<strong>on</strong> models, the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

regressi<strong>on</strong>s for the effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household yearly self employment income<br />

from livestock are shown in Table 6 (Appendix A). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> fixed effect, n<strong>on</strong>fixed effects,<br />

naïve and super-naive estimates are all positive for the coefficient <strong>on</strong> the m<strong>on</strong>th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

35 Most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> rental expenditure comes from rental <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> self-employment activities such as rental <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> rice field for<br />

planting rice, rental <strong>on</strong> shop for trading and rental <strong>on</strong> garage for vehicles fixing service.<br />

59


savings group membership, implying that savings group participati<strong>on</strong> by a member <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

household increases the yearly income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household livestock producti<strong>on</strong>. Only two<br />

estimati<strong>on</strong> models, fixed effects and n<strong>on</strong>fixed effects, produce statistically significant for<br />

that coefficient at the 10 per cent level, (19,962.47; p = 0.0606) and (19,962.47; p =<br />

0.0640) respectively. In c<strong>on</strong>trast, those results were not significant in the study by<br />

Coleman (1999) <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the village bank in Northeast Thailand.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household also has a positive and significant effect <strong>on</strong> household<br />

annual self employment income from livestock. Table 6 (Appendix A) showed all<br />

positive relati<strong>on</strong>ship <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household size to the yearly income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

household from livestock producti<strong>on</strong> by employing all four estimati<strong>on</strong> models, and these<br />

coefficients are statistically significant at the 1 per cent level. It implies that more<br />

member in the household could increase the annual income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household from livestock<br />

producti<strong>on</strong>. For example, in case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fixed effects estimati<strong>on</strong> model, increase in<br />

household size by <strong>on</strong>e pers<strong>on</strong> could push up the household yearly income from livestock<br />

producti<strong>on</strong> by 318,013 Kip.<br />

<strong>Household</strong> which had a chief or member <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group committee had a<br />

large increase in the household yearly income from livestock producti<strong>on</strong>. It can be seen<br />

that all four estimati<strong>on</strong> models result in the positive coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the variable for<br />

household which has chief or member <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group committee, which are statistically<br />

significant at the 1 per cent level as shown in Table 6 (Appendix A).<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, Table 6 (Appendix A) shows that the fixed effects estimates produce<br />

positive coefficients <strong>on</strong> the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> civil servants in the household which is significant<br />

at the 10 per cent level (413,843.2; p = 0.0979).<br />

60


6.2.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g>s <strong>on</strong> household annual self employment income from<br />

agriculture<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> estimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group impact <strong>on</strong> household yearly income from<br />

agriculture producti<strong>on</strong> is also d<strong>on</strong>e employing equati<strong>on</strong> (11) with the four specificati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Table 7 (Appendix A) shows that all four estimati<strong>on</strong> models result in significant negative<br />

correlati<strong>on</strong> between the m<strong>on</strong>th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group membership and the yearly income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

household from agriculture producti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the m<strong>on</strong>th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group<br />

membership in the four models are significant at the 1 per cent level. However, the study<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Coleman (1999) did not find any significant relati<strong>on</strong>ship between the m<strong>on</strong>th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> village<br />

bank membership and household agriculture producti<strong>on</strong>, corresp<strong>on</strong>ding to the four<br />

models.<br />

Although there is negative relati<strong>on</strong> between the m<strong>on</strong>th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group<br />

membership and the household income from agricultural self-employment activities, this<br />

result is still ambiguous. It is difficult to c<strong>on</strong>clude that the participati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group<br />

decreases the household income from the agricultural self-employment activities, because<br />

such a negative relati<strong>on</strong>ship <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficient may have other reas<strong>on</strong>s behind it. One<br />

possibility accounting for this negative relati<strong>on</strong>ship is prices <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> agricultural products<br />

which fluctuate throughout the year. Another possibility is related to underestimated real<br />

household income from agricultural self-employment activities. This can be explained as<br />

data <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the yearly household collecting <strong>on</strong>ly from a part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> agricultural products sold in<br />

the markets that are excludes the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> agriculture products for the owner’s household<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> and those reserved for reproducing (cultivating). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> annual household<br />

income from the agricultural self-employment activities shown in the regressi<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

61


therefore, is lower than the real value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the agriculture products. Some sample<br />

households had a zero value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household income from the agriculture products because<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the n<strong>on</strong>-sale <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> agricultural products (<strong>on</strong>ly used for household c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>), even<br />

though they produced those products. This was particularly the case for households who<br />

rented the rice fields for plantati<strong>on</strong> 36 .<br />

Member dummy variable is positive and significant in relati<strong>on</strong> to the yearly<br />

income from household agricultural producti<strong>on</strong>. Its coefficient is large and significant<br />

(286,830.8; p = 0.0808) for the fixed effects estimati<strong>on</strong> model and (286,830.8; p =<br />

0.0847) for the n<strong>on</strong>fixed effects estimati<strong>on</strong> model. This implies that unobservable<br />

differences between member and n<strong>on</strong>members have large c<strong>on</strong>sequences. In other word,<br />

being member <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group can increase the yearly income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household agricultural<br />

producti<strong>on</strong>. In c<strong>on</strong>trast, in the study by Coleman (1999), there is an insignificant relati<strong>on</strong><br />

between member dummy variable and household agricultural producti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Having a female household head has a negative and significant relati<strong>on</strong>ship to the<br />

yearly income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household agricultural producti<strong>on</strong>, corresp<strong>on</strong>ding to the four estimati<strong>on</strong><br />

models. Its coefficient is statistically significant at the 1 per cent level for all cases <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

estimati<strong>on</strong>s as shown in Table 7 (Appendix A). This result shows that household head<br />

who is not female crucially increase the annual income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household agricultural<br />

producti<strong>on</strong>. This may be true because, in rice plantati<strong>on</strong>, heavy tasks like ploughing or<br />

harrowing are mainly men’s work, while it is the women who select the seed, uproot<br />

seedlings, transplant and weed (Kunkel and Seibel, 1997:106).<br />

36 Most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> them did not sell their rice, <strong>on</strong>ly for own c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>, after payment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the rental fee to landlord<br />

by some amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> rice, regarding to the agreement between landowner and leasee.<br />

62


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the household and the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>ths doing business has a positive<br />

and significant relati<strong>on</strong>ship to the yearly income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household agricultural producti<strong>on</strong> as<br />

can be seen from the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all four estimati<strong>on</strong> models. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir coefficients are<br />

statistically significant at the 1 per cent level as shown in Table 7 (Appendix A).<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> generati<strong>on</strong>s that the family has been in the village has a positive<br />

impact <strong>on</strong> the yearly income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household agricultural producti<strong>on</strong>. Its coefficient is<br />

significant at the 5 per cent level. It means that more number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> generati<strong>on</strong>s’ family in<br />

village can help agriculture work to push more products, and then household income may<br />

increase.<br />

It is not surprising that the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned land 5 years ago or initial<br />

wealth has positive effect <strong>on</strong> the yearly income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household agricultural producti<strong>on</strong><br />

because land is essential capital for agricultural plantati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Focus <strong>on</strong> the variable <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> village characteristic, the distance from the village to<br />

main market has a negative effect <strong>on</strong> the annual income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household agricultural<br />

producti<strong>on</strong>. This is true in reality because if goods, especially agricultural products, are<br />

located far away from the market (city market), their price are lower than the <strong>on</strong>es sold in<br />

the main market.<br />

6.2.3 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g>s <strong>on</strong> household m<strong>on</strong>thly rental expenditure<br />

Table 8 (Appendix A) show the regressi<strong>on</strong> results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the equati<strong>on</strong> (11) <strong>on</strong><br />

household m<strong>on</strong>thly rental expenditure corresp<strong>on</strong>ding to the fixed effects, n<strong>on</strong>fixed effects,<br />

naïve and super-naïve models. All four models indicate the positive correlati<strong>on</strong> between<br />

the m<strong>on</strong>th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group membership and the household m<strong>on</strong>thly rental expenditure.<br />

63


Its coefficient is significant at the 5 per cent level for the first three specificati<strong>on</strong>s and at<br />

the 1 per cent level for the super-naïve model. This result could be interpreted as showing<br />

that the participati<strong>on</strong> in a savings group leads to increase in household m<strong>on</strong>thly rental<br />

expenditure. In other words, the savings group participati<strong>on</strong> supports the pers<strong>on</strong>s who<br />

have no physical assets to run household self-employment activities such as rice<br />

plantati<strong>on</strong> and opening a shop for trading.<br />

Educati<strong>on</strong> level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals in the household also has a positive and significant<br />

impact <strong>on</strong> household m<strong>on</strong>thly rental expenditure. Its coefficient is statistically significant<br />

at the 5 per cent level for all four estimati<strong>on</strong> models. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> result could be explained by the<br />

fact that people who achieve high educati<strong>on</strong> level could be more c<strong>on</strong>fident to do their<br />

business in new ways walkout investing their own capital (especially physical asset).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y<br />

c<strong>on</strong>duct their business by renting or leasing assets.<br />

6.3 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> educati<strong>on</strong><br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> educati<strong>on</strong> can be seen from household m<strong>on</strong>thly<br />

educati<strong>on</strong>al expenditure. Table 9 (Appendix A) shows the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong><br />

household m<strong>on</strong>thly educati<strong>on</strong>al expenditure by regressing the equati<strong>on</strong> (11) with respect<br />

to the four specificati<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group membership has positive relati<strong>on</strong><br />

to the household m<strong>on</strong>thly educati<strong>on</strong>al expenditure. Its coefficient is significant at the 5<br />

per cent level for the four estimati<strong>on</strong> models. This relati<strong>on</strong>ship indicates that the<br />

participati<strong>on</strong> in a savings group can increase the m<strong>on</strong>thly educati<strong>on</strong>al expenditure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

household. It can be seen that being member <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group for <strong>on</strong>e more m<strong>on</strong>th could<br />

raise the household m<strong>on</strong>thly educati<strong>on</strong> expenditure by 5,670 Kip, in case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fixed<br />

64


effects model, for example. One can say that the people joining savings group can<br />

support for their children’s schooling. However, this result could not be found in the<br />

study by Coleman (1999).<br />

Turning to village characteristic variables, the village which has a primary school<br />

until grade 5 has a positively significant effect <strong>on</strong> the household m<strong>on</strong>thly educati<strong>on</strong><br />

expenses. Table 9 (Appendix A) shows that the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this variable with<br />

statistically significant level at the 10 per cent, corresp<strong>on</strong>ding to the n<strong>on</strong>fixed effects,<br />

naïve and super naïve models. This result implies that a village which has a primary<br />

school until grade 5 can support more children to c<strong>on</strong>tinue their schooling until higher<br />

educati<strong>on</strong> level.<br />

To c<strong>on</strong>clude, there are many positive impacts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group participati<strong>on</strong> at<br />

household level. This is seen by applying the fixed effects, n<strong>on</strong>fixed effects, naïve and<br />

super-naïve estimati<strong>on</strong> models. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se household impacts are shown in three categories,<br />

namely household assets, household self-employment activities and educati<strong>on</strong>. However,<br />

some theoretically fundamental relati<strong>on</strong>ship results might present the adverse effects<br />

from such as the negative relati<strong>on</strong>ship between the m<strong>on</strong>ths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group membership<br />

and the household income from agricultural self-employment activities. This is more<br />

likely related to data collecti<strong>on</strong> issues.<br />

However, this paper has some limitati<strong>on</strong>s. First, even though this applied the<br />

generalized least squares estimati<strong>on</strong> (GLS) to correct heteroskedasticity, called weighted<br />

least squares (WLS) estimati<strong>on</strong>s, there may be correlati<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g independent variables.<br />

This may lead to biased estimati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <strong>on</strong> household outcomes. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, there<br />

may be endogenous issue in variables because this study did not cover a test for the<br />

65


endogeneity. Third, this study did not take into account the spillover effects to<br />

n<strong>on</strong>members in the six villages. Fourth, the values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> data <strong>on</strong> household assets, incomes<br />

and expenditures are nominal. Fifth, the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cross-secti<strong>on</strong> data to evaluate the impact<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group, may show <strong>on</strong>ly the short term effect and may not predict the l<strong>on</strong>g<br />

term impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group which may be possible to ascertain by using panel data.<br />

This is a suggested area for further research.<br />

66


CHAPTER 7<br />

CONCLUSION<br />

Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance affects household welfare or outcome through a number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> channels.<br />

Research studies have showed that micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance has significant impact <strong>on</strong> assets, income,<br />

expenditure, educati<strong>on</strong>al status, health as well as gender empowerment. In this paper, the<br />

effects <strong>on</strong> household outcomes by the participati<strong>on</strong> in the savings group in a semi-urban<br />

area <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos were estimated by applicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the survey design and research<br />

methodology <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Coleman (1999) taking into account bias for self-selecti<strong>on</strong> and<br />

endogenous program placement which was not corrected in the previous studies relating<br />

to Laos. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> survey sample included members and n<strong>on</strong>members in six villages that have<br />

own savings groups. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se savings group were in operati<strong>on</strong> for various lengths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> time.<br />

Members who experienced benefits from joining the savings group by either obtaining a<br />

credit or receiving a dividend are called the “treatment” group, and those who have not<br />

benefited from the groups are called the “c<strong>on</strong>trol” group. All members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the “c<strong>on</strong>trol”<br />

group were relatively new members with an average membership <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 2.2 m<strong>on</strong>ths. In order<br />

to dem<strong>on</strong>strate the importance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> selecti<strong>on</strong> bias correcti<strong>on</strong>, the paper compared the results<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the “correct” empirical specificati<strong>on</strong> to those <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the three other specificati<strong>on</strong>s which do<br />

not take account for some or all <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the bias.<br />

This paper provides estimates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> participati<strong>on</strong> in the savings<br />

group <strong>on</strong> household house value, household livestock producti<strong>on</strong> income, household<br />

agriculture producti<strong>on</strong> income, household rental expenses, and household educati<strong>on</strong><br />

67


expenses by applying four empirical specificati<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> empirical results illustrate that<br />

the participati<strong>on</strong> in the savings groups has large positive and significant effects <strong>on</strong> all <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

these outcomes, except household agriculture producti<strong>on</strong> income. This may be explained<br />

by the fluctuati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> seas<strong>on</strong>al agricultural prices, and under reporting <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the real value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

household agricultural income. This is because data collected pertain <strong>on</strong>ly to income<br />

from agriculture products which were sold in the markets, not those used for self-<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this study differ from those <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Coleman (1999). He did not find<br />

significant impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> village bank loan <strong>on</strong> household outcomes <strong>on</strong>ce correcti<strong>on</strong>s were<br />

made for self-selecti<strong>on</strong> and endogenous program placement. Only the more “naive”<br />

specificati<strong>on</strong>s (i.e. without these correcti<strong>on</strong>s) significantly overestimate program impact.<br />

This difference in the results between this study and Coleman’s (1999) study may come<br />

from the different c<strong>on</strong>texts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these two cases, even though these two cases follow the<br />

same village bank model (see Appendix B: secti<strong>on</strong> 2.2.1). Regarding to Coleman’s<br />

results, he provided some explanati<strong>on</strong>s as:<br />

Thailand…is a relatively wealthy developing country, with annual GDP growth at<br />

close to 10% for the past two decades, and many villagers already have access to<br />

low-interest credit from financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s such as the BAAC 37 . In fact, the<br />

average wealth <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> survey households was 529,586 baht, and average household<br />

low-interest debt, excluding village bank debt, was 31,330 baht, <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> which 9,342<br />

baht was held by women. In such an envir<strong>on</strong>ment, it should not be surprising that<br />

loans <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1,500 to 7,500 baht would have a negligible impact. Indeed, a comm<strong>on</strong><br />

complaint <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> women surveyed was that the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> village bank loans was far too<br />

small for them to be productive. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> village bank model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> group lending, as<br />

practiced throughout the world, sometimes takes a “<strong>on</strong>e size fits all” approach,<br />

based <strong>on</strong> a first loan <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> US$50 and a maximum <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> US$300. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se limits are in<br />

fact comm<strong>on</strong>ly used in much poorer countries in Africa, where they represent a<br />

37<br />

BAAC stands for the semi-statal Bank for Agriculture and Agricultural Cooperatives (Coleman, 1999:<br />

111).<br />

68


lot <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>ey to a village household. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are also the limits used in Northeast<br />

Thai villages, and they are arguably too low. On the other hand, the significant<br />

number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> members who had worked themselves into debt by borrowing without<br />

having identified a productive activity to invest in points to the need for project<br />

field staff to redouble efforts to stress the need to invest the loans productively<br />

(Coleman, 1999:133).<br />

In c<strong>on</strong>trast to Thailand, Laos is <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poorest countries in East Asia with an<br />

estimated per capita income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> US$ 390 in 2004. Real GDP grew by an annual average<br />

rate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 6.3 per cent in the 1990s and was 7 per cent in 2005 (World Bank Vientiane<br />

Office, 2006). In terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> access to financial services, about <strong>on</strong>e milli<strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omically<br />

active people potentially require access to formal or semi-formal micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance services.<br />

However, almost three quarters cannot reach them. Approximately 300,000 people<br />

recently accessed loan and savings services. Only 21 per cent have access to microcredit<br />

from the formal sector, 33 per cent are dependant <strong>on</strong> the semi-formal sector and project<br />

initiatives and the rest 46 per cent are obtaining financial service from the informal sector.<br />

In this survey sample, <strong>on</strong>ly 6 per cent and 4 per cent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> those sample surveyed access<br />

could credit at low interest rates and make deposits with APB respectively (Appendix B:<br />

Table 5-6). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se may be factors that lead to the villagers’ need for a credit for<br />

productive purpose from the savings group. This may, therefore, lead to have a<br />

significant impact <strong>on</strong> their household outcomes.<br />

This paper also has some limitati<strong>on</strong>s. First, even though this applied the<br />

generalized least squares estimati<strong>on</strong> (GLS) to correct heteroskedasticity, called weighted<br />

least squares (WLS) estimati<strong>on</strong>s, there may be correlati<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g independent variables.<br />

This may lead to biased estimati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <strong>on</strong> household outcomes. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, there<br />

may be endogenous issue in variables because this study did not cover a test for the<br />

69


endogeneity. Third, this study did not take into account the spillover effects to<br />

n<strong>on</strong>members in the six villages. Fourth, the values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> data <strong>on</strong> household assets, incomes<br />

and expenditures are nominal. Fifth, the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cross-secti<strong>on</strong> data to evaluate the impact<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group, may show <strong>on</strong>ly the short term effect and may not predict the l<strong>on</strong>g term<br />

impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group which may be possible to ascertain by using panel data.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> panel data for c<strong>on</strong>ducting a follow up survey for an impact analysis is<br />

recommended area for further study. This will help in dealing with problems such<br />

spillover effects and endogeneity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> explanatory variables.<br />

However, this paper’s findings have several important implicati<strong>on</strong>s. Firstly, the<br />

large positive impact savings group has <strong>on</strong> household asset suggest that micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance<br />

programs may improve household status in term <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> wealth. Sec<strong>on</strong>dly, the positive<br />

significant effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group <strong>on</strong> productivity, particularly livestock and<br />

agriculture in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> rental <strong>on</strong> rice fields, suggest that the savings group program may<br />

be a viable strategy for the poverty eradicati<strong>on</strong>. This is c<strong>on</strong>sistent with the Nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

Growth and Poverty Eradicati<strong>on</strong> Strategy (NGPES) (2004: 65) <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Government <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao<br />

PDR which recognizes the importance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance and has placed it as the <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

high priority projects for the agriculture and forestry development plan. Thirdly, the great<br />

positive influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group program <strong>on</strong> household educati<strong>on</strong> expenses<br />

suggests that micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance program may be <strong>on</strong>e viable strategy to reach the millennium<br />

development goals in term <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

70


References<br />

Materials in English<br />

Aghi<strong>on</strong>, Beatriz Armendariz and J<strong>on</strong>athan Morduch, 2005, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance, L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>, England: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> MIT Press.<br />

Asian Coaliti<strong>on</strong> for Housing Rights, 2005, Laos Grassroots Savings Network: Part 2,<br />

Update: 7 th December 2005, Retrieved June 9, 2006, from<br />

http://www.achr.net/Countries/Laos/LaoSavingss2.htm.<br />

Bagchi, Palash K., Sarah Wood, and Phetdav<strong>on</strong>e Chaleunsouk, 2002, “Market Research<br />

Study: A Sector Analysis Update for Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance in Lao PDR,” Lao PDR:<br />

C<strong>on</strong>cern Worldwide, July, unpublished.<br />

Baker, Judy L. 2000, Evaluating the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Development Projects <strong>on</strong> Poverty: A<br />

Handbook for Practiti<strong>on</strong>ers, Washingt<strong>on</strong> DC: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank.<br />

Bank <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Thailand, 2006, Table 89: Rates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Exchange <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Commercial Banks in Bangkok<br />

Metropolis, Retrieved June 9, 2006, from http://www.bot.or.th/bothomepage<br />

/databank/Ec<strong>on</strong>Data/Ec<strong>on</strong>Finance/Download/Tab89.xls.<br />

Bank <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Lao PDR, 2002, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Banking and Financial Sector <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao PDR: Financial<br />

Sector Note, Vientiane, Laos: the Bank <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao PDR, 15 July.<br />

Barnes, Carolyn, 1996, Assets and <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Microenterprise Finance Programs,<br />

Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC: Management System Internati<strong>on</strong>al.<br />

Chanleunsinh, Chansathith, 2004, “Village Savings Groups in Lao PDR: Factors<br />

affecting their Growth: Case study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> FIAM/CODI Savings Group projects in<br />

Vientiane Capital/Municipality”. Nati<strong>on</strong>al Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research Institute, Vientiane,<br />

Laos, 10th December, unpublished.<br />

71


Chowdhury, A.M.R., and Bhuiya, A. 2004, “<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Wider <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> BRAC Poverty<br />

Alleviati<strong>on</strong> Programme in Bangladesh,” Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Development,<br />

16: 369-386.<br />

Coleman, Brett E., 2002, “Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance in Northeast Thailand: Who Benefits and How<br />

Much?” Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Research Department Working Paper no.9, Asian<br />

Development Bank, April.<br />

Coleman, Brett E., 1999, “<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> group lending in Northeast Thailand,” Journal<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Development Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 60: 105-141.<br />

Copestake, J., 2002, “Inequality and <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Polarizing <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Microcredit: Evidence<br />

from Zambia’s Copperbelt,” Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Development 14: 743-755.<br />

Copestake, J., Bhalotra, S., and Johns<strong>on</strong>, S., 2001, “Assessing the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Microcredit:<br />

A Zambian Case Study” <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Development Studies 37 (4): 81-100.<br />

Enterplan, 2003, “Towards s Strategy to Promote Rural and Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance,” FIRST<br />

Initiative, Lao PDR: Development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a Rural and Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance Strategy and<br />

Legal and Regulatory Framework, June, unpublished.<br />

Gaile, L.Gary and Jennifer Foster, 1996, Review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Methodological Approach to the<br />

Study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Microenterprise Credit Programs, Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC:<br />

Management System Internati<strong>on</strong>al.<br />

Gersovitz, Mark, 1983, “Savings and Nutriti<strong>on</strong> at Low Incomes,” Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political<br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 91(5): 841-855.<br />

Goetz, A.M., & Gupta, R.S. 1996, “Who Takes the Credit? Gender, Power, and C<strong>on</strong>trol<br />

Over Loan Use in Rural Credit Programs in Bangladesh,” World Development 24<br />

(1): 45-63.<br />

72


Greene, William H. 2000, Ec<strong>on</strong>ometric Analysis, Upper Saddle River, New Jersey:<br />

Prentice-Hall Press.<br />

Hashemi, S.M., Schuler, S.R., Riley, A.P., 1996, “Rural Credit Programs and Women’s<br />

Empowerment in Bangladesh,” World Development 24 (4): 635-653.<br />

Heckman, James J. and Richard Robb, 1985, “Alternative Methods for Evaluating the<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Interventi<strong>on</strong>s: An Overview,” Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>ometrics 30: 239-386.<br />

Holvoet, Nathalie, 2004, “<str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance Program <strong>on</strong> Children’s Educati<strong>on</strong>: Do<br />

the Gender <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Borrower and the Delivery Model Matter?” Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance 6(2): 27-49.<br />

Hulme David and Mosley Paul, 1996, Finance Against Poverty, 1rst and 2 nd Vols.<br />

L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Routledge.<br />

Hulme, D., 2000, “<str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> Assessment Methodologies for Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory,<br />

Experience and Better Practice,” World Development 28 (1): 79-98.<br />

Khandker, S.R., Samad, H.A., and Khan, Z.H. 1998, “Income and Employment Effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance-credit Programmes: Village-level Evidence from Bangladesh,” <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Development Studies 35 (2): 96-124.<br />

Khandker, Shahidur R, 2003, “Micro-Finance and Poverty: Evidence Using Panel Data<br />

from Bangladesh,” Policy Research Working Paper 2945, World Bank,<br />

Washingt<strong>on</strong> DC.<br />

Kunkel, C.R. and H.D. Seibel, 1997, Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance in Laos, Bangkok, Thailand: Asia<br />

Pacific Rural and Agricultural Credit Associati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

73


Kyophilav<strong>on</strong>g, Phouphet and Chansathith Chaleunsinh, 2005, “<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Savings<br />

Group and Its Service Issues in Laos,” Lao Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Business<br />

Management 1(3): 43-66.<br />

Ledgerwood, Joanna, 2002, Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance Handbook: An Instituti<strong>on</strong>al and Financial<br />

Perspective, Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: World Bank, Sustainable Banking with the Poor<br />

project.<br />

McKernan, Signe-Mary, 2002, “<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Microcredit Programs <strong>on</strong> Self-<br />

Employment Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>its: Do N<strong>on</strong>credit Program Aspects Matter?” <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Statistics 84(1): 93-115.<br />

Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance Capacity Building & Research Programme, 2005, Rural & Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance<br />

Statistics in Lao PDR 2004, Vientiane, Lao PDR: Nati<strong>on</strong>al Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research<br />

Institute, and C<strong>on</strong>cern Worldwide Lao PDR.<br />

M<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fitt, Robert, 1991, “Program Evaluati<strong>on</strong> with N<strong>on</strong>experimental Data,” Evaluati<strong>on</strong><br />

Review, 15(3): 291-314.<br />

M<strong>on</strong>tgomery, R., Debapriya Bhattacharya, and David Hulme, 1996, “Credit for <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poor<br />

in Bangladesh: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> BRAC Rural Development Programme and <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Government<br />

Thana Resource Development and Employment Programme,” chapter 12 in<br />

Finance Against Poverty. David Hulme and Paul Mosley, eds. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Routledge.<br />

Morduch, J. 1998, “Does Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance Really Help the Poor? New Evidence from<br />

Flagship Programs in Bangladesh,” First complete draft. Retrieved June 3, 2006,<br />

from http://www.wws.princet<strong>on</strong>.edu/~rpds/downloads/morduch_micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance<br />

_poor.pdf.<br />

74


Mosley, Paul, 1997, “<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>trol Groups in <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> Assessments for<br />

Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance,” Social Finance Unit Working Paper No. 19, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

Labour Office, Geneva.<br />

Mosley, Paul, 2001, “Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance and Poverty in Bolivia,” <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Development<br />

Studies 37(4): 101-132.<br />

Nati<strong>on</strong>al Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research Institute, 2004, Rural & Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance Statistic in Laos<br />

2003, Vientiane, Laos: Nati<strong>on</strong>al Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research Institute.<br />

Nati<strong>on</strong>al Growth and Poverty Eradicati<strong>on</strong> Strategy, 2004, Vientiane, Lao PDR., June.<br />

Pitt, M.M., and Khandker, S. R., 1996, “<strong>Household</strong> and Intrahousehold <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

Grameen Bank and Similar Targeted Credit Programs in Bangladesh,” World<br />

Bank Discusssi<strong>on</strong> Papers 320, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank, Washingt<strong>on</strong> DC.<br />

Pitt, M.M., Khandker, S.R., Mckernan, S.M., & Latif, M.A, 1999, “Credit Programs for<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poor and Reproductive Behavior in Low-Income Countries: Are the Reported<br />

Causal Relati<strong>on</strong>ships the Result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Heterogeneity Bias?” Demography 36 (1): 1-<br />

21.<br />

Pitt, Mark M., and Shahidur R. Khandker, 1998, “<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Group-Based Credit<br />

Programs <strong>on</strong> Poor <strong>Household</strong>s in Bangladesh: Does the Gender <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Participants<br />

Matter?” Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy, 106 (5): 958-996.<br />

Rashid, Mansoora and Robert M. Townsend, 1994, “Targeting Credit and Insurance:<br />

Efficiency, Mechanism <strong>Design</strong> and Program Evaluati<strong>on</strong>,” ESP Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper<br />

No. 47, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank, Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC.<br />

Ravalli<strong>on</strong>, Martin, 2005, “Evaluating Anti-Poverty Programs,” Policy Research Working<br />

Paper 3625, World Bank, Washingt<strong>on</strong> DC.<br />

75


Robins<strong>on</strong>, Marguerite S, 2001, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance Revoluti<strong>on</strong>, Sustainable Finance for the<br />

Poor, Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: World Bank.<br />

Schenk-Sandbergen, Loes and Outhaki Choulamany-Khamphoui, 1995, Women in Rice<br />

Field and Offices: Irrigati<strong>on</strong> in Laos. Gender Specific Case Studies in Four<br />

Villages, Heiloo (<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Netherlands): Empowerment.<br />

Shaw, J., 2004, “Microenterprise Occupati<strong>on</strong> and Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong> in Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance<br />

Programs: Evidence from Sri Lanka,” World Development 32 (7): 1247-1264.<br />

Sichanth<strong>on</strong>gthip, Chanhsana, 2004, Loan Repayment and <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Income in Lao<br />

Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance: Saithani Case, (Master thesis, Sophia University, 2004). Japan:<br />

Sophia University.<br />

Slover, Curtis, J<strong>on</strong> Wynne Williams, Jose Gars<strong>on</strong>, and Eric Duflos, 1997, Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance<br />

in Rural Lao PDR: A Nati<strong>on</strong>al Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ile, United Nati<strong>on</strong>s Development Programme<br />

and United Nati<strong>on</strong>s Capital Development Fund, June.<br />

United Nati<strong>on</strong>s Capital Development Fund, 2001, Feasibility Study Missi<strong>on</strong> Report:<br />

Micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance & Sustainable Livelihood, UNDP/UNCDF LAO/96/CO1 –<br />

LAO/96/020, 25 th January, Retrieve July 7, 2006, from United Nati<strong>on</strong>s Capital<br />

Development Fund Web site: http://www.uncdf.org/english/countries/laos/<br />

micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance/technical_review_reports/FEA.pdf.<br />

Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. 2003, Introductory Ec<strong>on</strong>ometrics: A Modern Approach, 2 nd ed.,<br />

South-Western.<br />

World Bank Vientiane Office, 2006, “Lao PDR Ec<strong>on</strong>omic M<strong>on</strong>itor,” Vientiane, Laos,<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank, April.<br />

76


Yunus Muhammad, 2001, Banker to <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poor: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Autobiography <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Muhamad Yunus,<br />

founder <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grammeen Bank, Dhaka, Bangladesh: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> University Press<br />

Limited.<br />

77


Materials in Lao<br />

£¤¡¾−¦‰¤À¦ó´£¸¾´À¢˜´Á¢¤¦¿ìñ®Á´È¨ò¤Á콧÷´§ö−, £øÈ´õ¡È¼¸¡ñ®¡÷<br />

È´êɺ−À¤ò−, (²ò´£˜¤êó<br />

01, −½£º−͸¤¸¼¤¥ñ−, ®Ò´ó¸ñ−êó), £¤¡¾−»È¸´´õì½¹¸È¾¤¦ø−¡¾−¦½¹½²ñ−Á´È¨ò¤<br />

Áì½ ¦½«¾®ñ−²ñ©ê½−¾§÷´§ö− (¯½Àê©Äê). [Women and Community’s<br />

Empowering Project, Savings Group Manual, 1st ed., Vientiane, n.d, Cooperative<br />

Project between Lao Women’s Uni<strong>on</strong> and Community Organizati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Development Institute (Thailand)]<br />

£¤¡¾−¦‰¤À¦ó´£¸¾´À¢˜´Á¢¤¦¿ìñ®Á´È¨ò¤Á콧÷´§ö−, 쾨¤¾−¡¾−¥ñ©ª˜¤¯½ªò®ñ©Â£¤<br />

¡¾−¦‰¤À¦ó´£¸¾´À¢˜´Á¢¤¦¿ìñ®Á´È¨ò¤Á콧÷´§ö−: ª÷ì¾ 2002 À«ò¤¡ñ−¨¾ 2005,<br />

(−½£º−͸¤¸¼¤¥ñ−, 2005), £¤¡¾−»È¸´´õì½¹¸È¾¤¦ø−¡¾−¦½¹½²ñ−Á´È¨ò¤ Áì½<br />

¦½«¾®ñ−²ñ©ê½−¾§÷´§ö− (¯½Àê©Äê). [Women and Community’s Empowering<br />

Project, Report <strong>on</strong> the Implementati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Women and Community’s Empowering<br />

Project: October 2002 - September 2005, Vientiane, 2005, Cooperative Project<br />

between Lao Women’s Uni<strong>on</strong> and Community Organizati<strong>on</strong>s Development<br />

Institute (Thailand)]<br />

¦ø−¡¾¤¦½¹½²ñ−Á´È¨ò¤ì¾¸ ¦.¯.¯ 쾸 Áì½ ¦½«¾®ñ−²ñ©ê½−¾§÷´§ö− (¯½Àê©Äê),<br />

¡÷ È´êɺ−À¤ò− ¡ñ®¡¾−Á¡ÉÄ¢¯ñ−¹¾£¸¾´ê÷¡¨¾¡: 쾨¤¾−¡¾−¦‰¤À¦ó´ Áì½¢½¹¨¾¨<br />

¡÷ú´êɺ−À¤ò− Ã− ¦.¯.¯ 쾸, (−½£º−͸¤¸¼¤¥ñ−, ®Ò´ó¸ñ−êó), ¦ø−¡¾−¦½¹½²ñ−<br />

78


Á´È¨ò¤ ¦.¯.¯ 쾸 Áì½ ¦½«¾®ñ−²ñ©ê½−¾§÷´§ö− (¯½Àê©Äê). [Lao Women’s<br />

Uni<strong>on</strong>: Lao PDR and Community Organizati<strong>on</strong>s Development Institute: Thailand,<br />

Savings Group and Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong>: Study <strong>on</strong> Promoti<strong>on</strong> and Expansi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Savings Group in Lao PDR, Vientiane, n.d, Lao Women’s Uni<strong>on</strong>: Lao PDR and<br />

Community Organizati<strong>on</strong>s Development Institute: Thailand, (unpublished)]<br />

79


Appendix A<br />

Table 1: Descriptive statistics for variables <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> whole sample size<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Dependent variables (in Kip unless stated<br />

otherwise):<br />

Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly food expenditure 417,481 300,000 2,100,000 20,000 329,570 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong>s m<strong>on</strong>thly rental expenditure 10,267 0.00 1,200,000 0 84,549 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly transportati<strong>on</strong> fee<br />

210,553 45,000 3,600,000 0 432,975 251<br />

expenditure<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly educati<strong>on</strong>al expenditure 167,807 55,000 3,000,000 0 333,357 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly clothing expenditure 136,084 58,333 1,200,000 0 184,019 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly medical expenditure 105,106 30,000 2,000,000 0 234,065 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly expenditure <strong>on</strong><br />

household utensils<br />

95,754 25,000 2,400,000 0 222,659 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly other major expenditure 91,748 25,000 3,500,000 0 316,805 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly total n<strong>on</strong>-food<br />

817,319 480,000 6,080,000 12,000 998,698 251<br />

expenditure<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly total expenditure 1,234,800 885,000 7,000,000 67,000 1,152,860 251<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned house 33,964,779 20,000,000 287,000,000 0 45,449,824 251<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned land 498,000,000 20,000,000 111,000,000,000 0 7,010,000,000 251<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned land and house 532,000,000 46,000,000 111,000,000,000 0 7,010,000,000 251<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned agriculture asset 2,524,714 0 70,000,000 0 7,606,691 251<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned livestock asset 5,549,922 400,000 220,000,000 0 19,242,134 251<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned other enterprise<br />

asset<br />

459,721 0 20,000,000 0 2,228,895 251<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned savings at house 1,242,315 200,000 107,000,000 0 7,490,676 251<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned other asset 3,458,696 0 190,000,000 0 14,566,528 251<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned n<strong>on</strong>-land and<br />

house asset<br />

13,235,368 4,100,000 338,000,000 0 33,072,800 251<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned total asset 545,000,000 55,270,000 111,000,000,000 300,000 7,020,000,000 251<br />

80


Appendix A<br />

Table 1: Descriptive statistics for variables <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> whole sample size (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Dependent variables (in Kip unless stated<br />

otherwise):<br />

Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from agriculture<br />

2,419,044 1,000,000 81,500,000 0 5,979,001 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from livestock<br />

1,578,175 300,000 30,000,000 0 3,486,485 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from handicraft & textile<br />

1,888,122 100,000 25,400,000 0 3,243,976 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from trading<br />

3,376,932 0 194,000,000 0 18,386,628 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from repairing& fixing service<br />

379,482 0 21,900,000 0 2,459,819 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income 1,648,562 0 190,000,000 0 15,460,301 251<br />

from rice mill & c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from vehicle service<br />

301,793 0 40,000,000 0 2,944,454 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> total yearly self employment<br />

income<br />

11,592,111 5,475,000 196,000,000 0 25,294,651 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly wage & salary income 2,205,797 0 24,000,000 0 3,799,600 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly income from remittance 407,822 0 19,068,600 0 1,704,379 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly rental income 79,084 0 10,800,000 0 738,221 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly m<strong>on</strong>etary items income 887,139 0 213,000,000 0 13,461,641 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly other income 21,514 0 3,600,000 0 253,644 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> total yearly n<strong>on</strong>-self employment<br />

income<br />

3,601,356 500,000 213,000,000 0 13,979,828 251<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly total income 15,193,467 8,200,000 213,000,000 380,000 28,634,965 251<br />

81


Appendix A<br />

Table 1: Descriptive statistics for variables <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> whole sample size (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Independent variables:<br />

M<strong>on</strong>ths as VSG member 8.08 1 36 0 12 251<br />

Does household has a VSG member?(0/1) 0.73 1 1 0 0.45 251<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned land 5 years ago 29,042,629 10,000,000 911,000,000 0 82,223,525 251<br />

Sex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household head (female=1) 0.0996 0.00 1 0 0.30 251<br />

Gender <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>dents (entrepreneur)<br />

(female=1)<br />

0.888 1 1 0 0.32 251<br />

Maximum educati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>dents<br />

4.90 5 19 0 3 251<br />

(entrepreneur) (years)<br />

<strong>Household</strong> size 5.51 5 12 1 2 251<br />

Age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>dents (entrepreneur) (years) 41 41 75 18 12 251<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>ths doing business 161 120 813 1 146 251<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Generati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> family in village 0.502 0 6 0 1 251<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relatives in village 2.42 1 40 0 4 251<br />

Are you member or head <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the group<br />

0.064 0 1 0 0.24 251<br />

committee? (0/1)<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> civil servant in household 0.267 0 4 0 0.56 251<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> wage employment in HH 1.08 1 5 0 1.19 251<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> school age in HH 1.57 2 6 0 1.26 251<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> dependent <strong>on</strong> your income in HH 2.64 2 10 0 1.67 251<br />

Village is near river (0/1) 0.434 0 1 0 0.50 251<br />

Village has pig p<strong>on</strong>d which has water<br />

throughout the year (0/1)<br />

0.375 0 1 0 0.48 251<br />

Village has either pig p<strong>on</strong>d which has water<br />

throughout the year or be near river (0/1)<br />

0.566 1 1 0 0.50 251<br />

Village is located in district capital (0/1) 0.096 0 1 0 0.29 251<br />

82


Appendix A<br />

Table 1: Descriptive statistics for variables <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> whole sample size (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Dependent variables (in Kip unless stated<br />

otherwise):<br />

Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Does village have paved road or near main<br />

road (Km 13 road)? (0/1)<br />

0.287 0 1 0 0.45 251<br />

Village has irrigati<strong>on</strong> (0/1) 0.191 0 1 0 0.39 251<br />

Does village have school until sec<strong>on</strong>dary<br />

level?(0/1)<br />

0.096 0 1 0 0.29 251<br />

Does village have primary school up to<br />

0.661 1 1 0 0.47 251<br />

grade5? (0/1)<br />

Distance from village to main markets 22 20 33 15 6.84 251<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e cattle 1,610,359 1,500,000 2,000,000 1,300,000 233,007 251<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e buffalo 3,260,956 3,250,000 4,000,000 2,500,000 524,051 251<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pig per Kg 14,596 11,667 25,000 10,000 5,097 251<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> duck per Kg 14,572 15,000 15,000 13,500 617 251<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> traditi<strong>on</strong>al chicken (Gailard) per Kg 18,857 19,000 20,000 18,000 896 251<br />

Daily wage for harvesting rice 18,307 20,000 30,000 0 9,339 251<br />

Daily wage for planting rice 27,875 35,000 50,000 0 18,081 251<br />

Daily wage for c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> 24,243 25,000 27,500 20,000 2,043 251<br />

Source: Author’s survey data, September 2005 and March 2006.<br />

83


Appendix A<br />

Table 2: Descriptive statistics for variables by treatment group<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Dependent variables (in Kip unless stated<br />

otherwise):<br />

Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly food expenditure 429,160 300,000 2,100,000 20,000 356,530 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong>s m<strong>on</strong>thly rental expenditure 2,061 0 210,000 0 18,594 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly transportati<strong>on</strong> fee<br />

209,551 66,000 2,790,000 0 376,340 131<br />

expenditure<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly educati<strong>on</strong>al expenditure 201,508 70,000 2,700,000 0 348,466 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly clothing expenditure 161,304 100,000 1,000,000 0 194,430 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly medical expenditure 119,523 30,000 2,000,000 0 246,709 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly expenditure <strong>on</strong><br />

household utensils<br />

98,393 25,000 2,400,000 0 241,647 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly other major expenditure 119,380 25,000 3,500,000 0 421,754 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly total n<strong>on</strong>-food<br />

911,720 615,000 5,900,000 44,500 1,036,465 131<br />

expenditure<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly total expenditure 1,340,880 1,000,000 7,000,000 67,000 1,197,825 131<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned house 36,757,225 25,000,000 267,000,000 500,000 43,616,512 131<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned land 43,986,808 25,000,000 500,000,000 0 66,102,737 131<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned land and house 80,744,034 56,303,000 700,000,000 500,000 94,659,232 131<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned agriculture asset 2,702,595 0 60,000,000 0 7,597,104 131<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned livestock asset 4,906,851 400,000 150,000,000 0 16,750,015 131<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned other enterprise<br />

asset<br />

412,977 0 18,000,000 0 2,081,643 131<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned savings at house 1,078,321 200,000 50,000,000 0 4,602,353 131<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned other asset 4,311,510 0 190,000,000 0 19,478,105 131<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned n<strong>on</strong>-land and<br />

house asset<br />

13,412,254 3,820,000 338,000,000 0 36,561,896 131<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned total asset 94,156,287 62,100,000 720,000,000 1,080,000 111,000,000 131<br />

84


Appendix A<br />

Table 2: Descriptive statistics for variables by treatment group (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Dependent variables (in Kip unless stated<br />

otherwise):<br />

Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from agriculture<br />

2,537,023 700,000 81,500,000 0 7,571,050 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from livestock<br />

1,466,794 500,000 15,000,000 0 2,435,613 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from handicraft & textile<br />

2,134,983 500,000 25,400,000 0 3,686,305 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from trading<br />

2,664,695 0 194,000,000 0 17,334,078 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from repairing& fixing service<br />

552,672 0 21,900,000 0 2,944,155 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income 1,703,733 0 150,000,000 0 13,617,852 131<br />

from rice mill & c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from vehicle service<br />

427,481 0 40,000,000 0 3,754,035 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> total yearly self employment<br />

income<br />

11,487,380 6,160,000 194,000,000 0 23,500,748 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly wage & salary income 2,327,977 0 19,720,000 0 3,842,135 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly income <strong>on</strong> remittance 448,352 0 19,068,600 0 1,945,576 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly rental income 102,290 0 10,800,000 0 954,863 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly m<strong>on</strong>etary items income 45,802 0 6,000,000 0 524,222 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly other income 27,481 0 3,600,000 0 314,534 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> total yearly n<strong>on</strong>-self employment<br />

income<br />

2,951,902 400,000 26,068,600 0 4,678,700 131<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly total income 14,439,282 8,520,000 194,000,000 1,000,000 23,505,613 131<br />

85


Appendix A<br />

Table 2: Descriptive statistics for variables by treatment group (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Independent variables:<br />

Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

M<strong>on</strong>ths as VSG member 15 15 36 1 12.51 131<br />

Does household has a VSG member?(0/1) 1 1 1 1 0.00 131<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned land 5 years ago 25,345,857 12,000,000 300,000,000 0 38,953,728 131<br />

Sex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household head (female=1) 0.09 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.29 131<br />

Gender <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>dents (entrepreneur)<br />

(female=1)<br />

0.92 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.27 131<br />

Maximum educati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>dents<br />

4.69 5.00 14.00 0.00 3.41 131<br />

(entrepreneur) (years)<br />

<strong>Household</strong> size 5.65 5.00 11.00 2.00 1.98 131<br />

Age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>dents (entrepreneur) (years) 42.29 43.00 68.00 21.00 10.74 131<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>ths doing business 155.19 120.00 531.00 1.00 137.00 131<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Generati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> family in village 0.50 0.00 6.00 0.00 1.01 131<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relatives in village 2.27 2.00 12.00 0.00 2.49 131<br />

Are you member or head <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the group<br />

0.08 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.28 131<br />

committee? (0/1)<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> civil servant in household 0.28 0.00 2.00 0.00 0.54 131<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> wage employment in HH 1.18 1.00 5.00 0.00 1.29 131<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> school age in HH 1.67 2.00 5.00 0.00 1.17 131<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> dependent <strong>on</strong> your income in HH 2.66 3.00 8.00 0.00 1.60 131<br />

Village is near river (0/1) 0.56 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.50 131<br />

Village has pig p<strong>on</strong>d which has water<br />

throughout the year(0/1)<br />

0.36 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.48 131<br />

Village has either pig p<strong>on</strong>d which has water<br />

throughout the year or be near river (0/1)<br />

0.62 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.49 131<br />

Village is located in district capital (0/1) 0.12 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.33 131<br />

86


Appendix A<br />

Table 2: Descriptive statistics for variables by treatment group (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Dependent variables (in Kip unless stated<br />

otherwise):<br />

Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Does village have paved road or near main<br />

road (Km 13 road)? (0/1)<br />

0.38 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.49 131<br />

Village has irrigati<strong>on</strong> (0/1) 0.26 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.44 131<br />

Does village have school until sec<strong>on</strong>dary<br />

level? (0/1)<br />

0.12 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.33 131<br />

Does village have primary school up to<br />

0.74 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.44 131<br />

grade5? (0/1)<br />

Distance from village to main markets 22.75 20.00 33.00 15.00 6.63 131<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e cattle 1,573,664 1,500,000 2,000,000 1,300,000 231,660 131<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e buffalo 3,270,992 3,250,000 4,000,000 2,500,000 579,322 131<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pig per Kg 15,485 11,667 25,000 10,000 5,334 131<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> duck per Kg 14,668 15,000 15,000 13,500 577 131<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> traditi<strong>on</strong>al chicken (Gailard) per Kg 18,985 19,000 20,000 18,000 928 131<br />

Daily wage for harvesting rice 18,168 20,000 30,000 0 8,091 131<br />

Daily wage for planting rice 32,664 40,000 50,000 0 17,081 131<br />

Daily wage for c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> 23,798 25,000 27,500 20,000 1,970 131<br />

Source: Author’s survey data, September 2005 and March 2006.<br />

87


Appendix A<br />

Table 3: Descriptive statistics for variables by c<strong>on</strong>trol group<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Dependent variables (in Kip unless stated<br />

otherwise):<br />

Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly food expenditure 435,058 300,000 1,640,000 20,000 354,763 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong>s m<strong>on</strong>thly rental expenditure 39,396 0 1,200,000 0 180,419 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly transportati<strong>on</strong> fee<br />

311,404 50,000 3,600,000 0 671,649 52<br />

expenditure<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly educati<strong>on</strong>al expenditure 129,619 73,334 870,000 0 182,782 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly clothing expenditure 95,556 45,834 510,000 0 110,758 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly medical expenditure 88,875 30,000 800,000 0 166,766 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly expenditure <strong>on</strong><br />

household utensils<br />

104,131 25,000 1,000,000 0 205,913 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly other major expenditure 79,058 30,000 700,000 0 143,501 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly total n<strong>on</strong>-food<br />

848,039 477,223 5,050,000 44,167 1,004,497 52<br />

expenditure<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly total expenditure 1,283,097 890,000 6,010,000 225,000 1,238,047 52<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned house 33,009,317 15,000,000 287,000,000 100,000 52,921,605 52<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned land 2,210,000,000 15,000,000 111,000,000,000 0 15,400,000,000 52<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned land and house 2,240,000,000 40,750,000 111,000,000,000 100,000 15,400,000,000 52<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned agriculture asset 3,156,410 0 70,000,000 0 10,603,436 52<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned livestock asset 8,011,365 500,000 220,000,000 0 30,604,352 52<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned other enterprise<br />

asset<br />

726,731 0 15,000,000 0 2,342,297 52<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned savings at house 574,519 195,000 5,000,000 0 967,112 52<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned other asset 1,887,392 0 23,944,385 0 5,072,488 52<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned n<strong>on</strong>-land and<br />

house asset<br />

14,356,418 4,950,000 244,000,000 0 35,608,003 52<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned total asset 2,260,000,000 52,800,000 111,000,000,000 348,000 15,400,000,000 52<br />

88


Appendix A<br />

Table 3: Descriptive statistics for variables by c<strong>on</strong>trol group (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Dependent variables (in Kip unless stated<br />

otherwise):<br />

Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from agriculture<br />

2,370,000 570,000 15,000,000 0 3,645,969 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from livestock<br />

1,580,385 250,000 24,000,000 0 3,852,912 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from handicraft & textile<br />

1,703,500 0 10,000,000 0 2,879,942 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from trading<br />

3,952,885 0 94,100,000 0 14,868,408 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from repairing& fixing service<br />

0 0 0 0 0 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income 19,231 0 1,000,000 0 138,675 52<br />

from rice mill & c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income<br />

from vehicle service<br />

0 0 0 0 0 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> total yearly self employment<br />

income<br />

9,626,000 5,050,000 113,000,000 0 17,829,858 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly wage & salary income 1,870,000 0 14,400,000 0 3,213,138 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly income from remittance 249,816 0 7,995,450 0 1,182,835 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly rental income 113,462 0 4,000,000 0 578,378 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly m<strong>on</strong>etary items income 38,462 0 2,000,000 0 277,350 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly other income 34,615 0 1,800,000 0 249,615 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> total yearly n<strong>on</strong>-self employment<br />

income<br />

2,306,355 900,000 14,400,000 0 3,238,564 52<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly total income 11,932,355 6,600,000 121,000,000 1,000,000 19,371,116 52<br />

89


Appendix A<br />

Table 3: Descriptive statistics for variables by c<strong>on</strong>trol group (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Independent variables:<br />

Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

M<strong>on</strong>ths as VSG member 0 0 0 0 0 52<br />

Does household has a VSG member?(0/1) 1 1 1 1 0 52<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned land 5 years ago 36,661,946 9,000,000 770,000,000 0 112,000,000 52<br />

Sex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household head (female=1) 0.13 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.34 52<br />

Gender <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>dents (entrepreneur)<br />

(female=1)<br />

0.88 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.32 52<br />

Maximum educati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>dents<br />

5.27 5.00 13.00 0.00 3.06 52<br />

(entrepreneur) (years)<br />

<strong>Household</strong> size 5.54 5.00 11.00 2.00 2.16 52<br />

Age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>dents (entrepreneur) (years) 38.63 35.50 68.00 18.00 13.53 52<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>ths doing business 161.06 110.50 813.00 2.00 162.29 52<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Generati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> family in village 0.50 0.00 4.00 0.00 0.98 52<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relatives in village 2.21 1.00 12.00 0.00 2.82 52<br />

Are you member or head <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the group<br />

0.10 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.30 52<br />

committee? (0/1)<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> civil servant in household 0.37 0.00 4.00 0.00 0.71 52<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> wage employment in HH 1.10 1.00 4.00 0.00 1.16 52<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> school age in HH 1.83 2.00 6.00 0.00 1.37 52<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> dependent <strong>on</strong> your income in HH 2.65 2.00 8.00 0.00 1.63 52<br />

Village is near river (0/1) 0.08 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.27 52<br />

Village has pig p<strong>on</strong>d which has water<br />

throughout the year (0/1)<br />

0.42 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.50 52<br />

Village has either pig p<strong>on</strong>d which has water<br />

throughout the year or be near river (0/1)<br />

0.44 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.50 52<br />

Village is located in district capital (0/1) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 52<br />

90


Appendix A<br />

Table 3: Descriptive statistics for variables by c<strong>on</strong>trol group (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Independent variables:<br />

Does village have paved road or near main<br />

road (Km 13 road)?<br />

0.02 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.14 52<br />

Village has irrigati<strong>on</strong> (0/1) 0.02 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.14 52<br />

Does village have school until sec<strong>on</strong>dary<br />

level? (0/1)<br />

0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 52<br />

Does village have primary school up to<br />

0.44 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.50 52<br />

grade5? (0/1)<br />

Distance from village to main markets 24 18 33 15 7.81 52<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e cattle 1,678,846 1,750,000 2,000,000 1,300,000 191,830 52<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e buffalo 3,134,615 3,000,000 4,000,000 2,500,000 298,942 52<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pig per Kg 11,484 10,833 20,000 10,000 2,303 52<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> duck per Kg 14,356 14,000 15,000 13,500 605 52<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> traditi<strong>on</strong>al chicken (Gailard) per Kg 18,288 18,000 20,000 18,000 572 52<br />

Daily wage for harvesting rice 15,769 25,000 30,000 0 12,887 52<br />

Daily wage for planting rice 11,913 15,000 50,000 0 12,764 52<br />

Daily wage for c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> 25,769 25,000 27,500 22,500 1,447 52<br />

Source: Author’s survey data, September 2005 and March 2006.<br />

91


Appendix A<br />

Table 4: Descriptive statistics for variables by n<strong>on</strong>member<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Dependent variables (in Kip unless stated<br />

otherwise):<br />

Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly food expenditure 381,539 300,000 1,140,000 30,000 247,036 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong>s m<strong>on</strong>thly rental expenditure 3,799 0 150,000 0 19,816 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly transportati<strong>on</strong> fee<br />

135,363 7,500 1,500,000 0 260,151 68<br />

expenditure<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly educati<strong>on</strong>al expenditure 132,086 32,500 3,000,000 0 385,963 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly clothing expenditure 118,490 50,000 1,200,000 0 202,077 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly medical expenditure 89,745 24,584 2,000,000 0 253,594 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly expenditure <strong>on</strong> household 84,265 25,000 1,200,000 0 198,019 68<br />

utensils<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly other major expenditure 48,221 20,000 600,000 0 100,743 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly total n<strong>on</strong>-food expenditure 611,968 358,833 6,080,000 12,000 899,020 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> m<strong>on</strong>thly total expenditure 993,507 702,500 6,230,000 129,000 962,150 68<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned house 29,315,860 19,000,000 267,000,000 0 42,974,388 68<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned land 66,232,290 10,000,000 2,420,000,000 0 294,000,000 68<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned land and house 95,548,151 30,000,000 2,450,000,000 0 299,000,000 68<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned agriculture asset 1,698,971 100,000 30,000,000 0 4,155,598 68<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned livestock asset 4,906,500 200,000 65,500,000 0 10,876,800 68<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned other enterprise asset 345,588 0 20,000,000 0 2,424,959 68<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned savings at house 2,068,912 150,000 107,000,000 0 12,902,080 68<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned other asset 3,017,360 0 23,656,050 0 5,697,910 68<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned n<strong>on</strong>-land and house<br />

asset<br />

12,037,331 4,825,000 131,000,000 0 22,803,727 68<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned total asset 108,000,000 41,215,000 2,460,000,000 300,000 303,000,000 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income from<br />

agriculture<br />

2,229,265 1,500,000 19,000,000 0 3,462,084 68<br />

92


Appendix A<br />

Table 4: Descriptive statistics for variables by n<strong>on</strong>member (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Dependent variables (in Kip unless stated<br />

otherwise):<br />

Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income from<br />

livestock<br />

1,791,059 175,000 30,000,000 0 4,740,913 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income from<br />

handicraft & textile<br />

1,553,735 0 11,000,000 0 2,515,442 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income from<br />

trading<br />

4,308,603 0 182,000,000 0 22,539,720 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income from<br />

repairing& fixing service<br />

336,029 0 19,200,000 0 2,363,542 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income from 2,788,235 0 190,000,000 0 22,992,377 68<br />

rice mill & c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly self employment income from<br />

vehicle service<br />

290,441 0 18,250,000 0 2,214,526 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> total yearly self employment income 13,297,368 5,000,000 196,000,000 0 32,677,643 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly wage & salary income 2,227,206 0 24,000,000 0 4,153,388 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly income from remittance 450,569 0 10,000,000 0 1,550,881 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly rental income 8,088 0 400,000 0 51,551 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly m<strong>on</strong>etary items income 3,156,941 0 213,000,000 0 25,853,716 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly other income 0 0 0 0 0.00 68<br />

<strong>Household</strong> total yearly n<strong>on</strong>-self employment 5,842,804 450,000 213,000,000 0 25,914,373 68<br />

income<br />

<strong>Household</strong> yearly total income 19,140,172 8,100,000 213,000,000 380,000 40,947,644 68<br />

Independent variables:<br />

M<strong>on</strong>ths as VSG member 0 0 0 0 0.00 68<br />

Does household has a VSG member?(0/1) 0 0 0 0 0.00 68<br />

93


Appendix A<br />

Table 4: Descriptive statistics for variables by n<strong>on</strong>member (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Independent variables<br />

Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household owned land 5 years ago 30,337,816 5,000,000 911,000,000 0 113,000,000 68<br />

Sex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household head (female=1) 0.09 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.29 68<br />

Gender <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>dents (entrepreneur) (female=1) 0.82 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.38 68<br />

Maximum educati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>dents<br />

5.01 5.00 19.00 0.00 3.92 68<br />

(entrepreneur) (years)<br />

<strong>Household</strong> size 5.24 5.00 12.00 1.00 2.25 68<br />

Age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>dents (entrepreneur) (years) 41 39 75 19 13.69 68<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>ths doing business 172 121 624 1 152.41 68<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Generati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> family in village 0.51 0.00 6.00 0.00 1.13 68<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relatives in village 2.87 1.50 40.00 0.00 5.27 68<br />

Are you member or head <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the group committee? 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 68<br />

(0/1)<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> civil servant in household 0.16 0.00 2.00 0.00 0.44 68<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> wage employment in HH 0.88 1.00 4.00 0.00 0.99 68<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> school age in HH 1.19 1.00 6.00 0.00 1.28 68<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> dependent <strong>on</strong> your income in HH 2.59 2.00 10.00 0.00 1.85 68<br />

Village is near river (0/1) 0.47 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.50 68<br />

Village has pig p<strong>on</strong>d which has water throughout<br />

the year (0/1)<br />

0.37 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.49 68<br />

Village has either pig p<strong>on</strong>d which has water<br />

throughout the year or be near river (0/1)<br />

0.56 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.50 68<br />

Village is located in district capital (0/1) 0.12 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.32 68<br />

Does village have paved road or near main road<br />

(Km 13 road)? (0/1)<br />

0.31 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.47 68<br />

Village has irrigati<strong>on</strong> (0/1) 0.19 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.40 68<br />

Does village have school until sec<strong>on</strong>dary level?<br />

(0/1)<br />

0.12 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.32 68<br />

94


Appendix A<br />

Table 4: Descriptive statistics for variables by n<strong>on</strong>member (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Variable descripti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Independent variables<br />

Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Observati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Does village have primary school up to grade5?<br />

(0/1)<br />

0.68 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.47 68<br />

Distance from village to main markets 20.97 20.00 33.00 15.00 6.30 68<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e cattle 1,628,676 1,500,000 2,000,000 1,300,000 252,645 68<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e buffalo 3,338,235 3,500,000 4,000,000 2,500,000 535,607 68<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pig per Kg 15,262 11,667 25,000 10,000 5,310 68<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> duck per Kg 14,551 15,000 15,000 13,500 664 68<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> traditi<strong>on</strong>al chicken (Gailard) per Kg 19,044 19,000 20,000 18,000 871 68<br />

Daily wage for harvesting rice 20,515 20,000 30,000 0 7,877 68<br />

Daily wage for planting rice 30,853 35,000 50,000 0 16,678 68<br />

Daily wage for c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> 23,934 25,000 27,500 20,000 2,040 68<br />

Source: Author’s survey data, September 2005 and March 2006.<br />

95


Appendix A<br />

Table 5: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household house value - GLS.<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std. Error<br />

M<strong>on</strong>ths as VSG<br />

member<br />

292,097 ** 147,784 292,097 * 149,683 335,021 *** 122,254 358,260 *** 123,456<br />

Does household<br />

have a VSG<br />

member?(0/1)<br />

1,481,225 3,606,033 1,481,225 3,652,365<br />

Sex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

household head<br />

(female=1)<br />

-8,395,409 6,494,524 -8,395,409 6,577,969 -8,192,279 6,446,844 -8,324,504 6,502,591<br />

Gender <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

individuals<br />

(entrepreneur)<br />

(female=1)<br />

14,021,407 ** 6,760,261 14,021,407 ** 6,847,120 14,277,586 ** 6,841,554 10,800,449 * 6,236,708<br />

Maximum<br />

educati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

individuals<br />

(entrepreneur)<br />

(years)<br />

854,694 ** 422,396 854,694 ** 427,823 875,203 ** 4,152,112 912,698 ** 405,066<br />

<strong>Household</strong> size 1,037,618 752,418 1,037,618 762,086 1,031,433 761,675 1,141,685 753,676<br />

Age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

individuals<br />

(entrepreneur)<br />

(years)<br />

312,418 ** 136,471 312,418 ** 138,225 317,848 ** 136,362 347,865 *** 137,941<br />

96


Appendix A<br />

Table 5: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household house value - GLS. (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

m<strong>on</strong>ths doing<br />

business<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Generati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

family in village<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

relatives in<br />

village<br />

Are you<br />

member or head<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the group<br />

committee?<br />

(0/1)<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> civil<br />

servant in<br />

household<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

household<br />

owned land 5<br />

years ago<br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std. Error<br />

29,502 *** 11,177 29,502 *** 11,321 29,811 *** 11,347 33,317 *** 11,108<br />

843,836 1,191,177 843,836 1,206,481 796,147 1,209,852 542,343 1,190,404<br />

1,552,376 *** 387,633 1,552,376 *** 392,613 1,548,088 *** 392,040 1,544,427 *** 381,940<br />

12,703,787 *** 4,169,217 12,703,787 *** 4,222,785 12,597,429 *** 4,225,101 12,995,561 *** 4,189,169<br />

5,058,192 3,566,208 5,058,192 3,612,029 5,216,180 3,483,950 5,351,551 3,463,556<br />

0.0688 0.0498 0.0688 0.0504 0.0697 0.0502<br />

97


Appendix A<br />

Table 5: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household house value - GLS. (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Village has<br />

either pig p<strong>on</strong>d<br />

which has water<br />

throughout the<br />

year or be near<br />

river (0/1)<br />

Does village<br />

have paved road<br />

or near main<br />

road (Km 13<br />

road)? (0/1)<br />

Does village<br />

have primary<br />

school up to<br />

grade5? (0/1)<br />

Distance from<br />

village to main<br />

markets<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

traditi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

chicken<br />

(Gailard) per<br />

Kg<br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std. Error<br />

-44,768,692 36,726,790 -45,892,240 36,782,065 -47,125,621 36,182,599<br />

-17,908,249 ** 7,655,365 -18,358,229 ** 7,784,479 -18,674,677 ** 7,906,479<br />

45,390,649 38,241,483 46,212,441 38,344,587 47,538,868 3,764,1126<br />

583,219 424,715 599,591 416,257 585,607 424,001<br />

-258 1,783 -429 1,846 -171 1,841<br />

98


Appendix A<br />

Table 5: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household house value - GLS. (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Daily wage for<br />

c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong><br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std. Error<br />

-1,018 1,542 -886 1,613 -977 1,613<br />

F-statistic= 2.858314 F-statistic=2.858314 F-statistic=3.044732 F-statistic=2.911104<br />

Prob(F-statistic)=<br />

0.000149<br />

Prob(F-statistic)= 0.000149 Prob(F-statistic)= 0.000080 Prob(F-statistic)= 0.000217<br />

R-squared=0.181513 R-squared=0.181513 R-squared=0.181768 R-squared=0.166006<br />

Note: the superscripts *** , ** and * denote rejecti<strong>on</strong> at 1 per cent, 5 per cent and 10 per cent critical values.<br />

Source: Author’s survey data, September 2005 and March 2006.<br />

99


Appendix A<br />

Table 6: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> yearly self-employment income from livestock - GLS.<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

M<strong>on</strong>ths as VSG<br />

member<br />

19,962 * 10,589 19,962 * 10,725 5,374 6,546 5,948 6,388<br />

Does household have<br />

a VSG member?(0/1)<br />

-557,276 358,369 -557,276 362,974<br />

Sex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household<br />

head (female=1)<br />

-300,623 207,914 -300,623 210,585 -368,213 * 204,348 -371,531 * 202,203<br />

Gender <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals<br />

(entrepreneur)<br />

(female=1)<br />

80,203 845,785 80,203 856,652 -6,467 855,017 -84,635 861,953<br />

Maximum educati<strong>on</strong><br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals<br />

(entrepreneur) (years)<br />

12,190 33,842 12,190 34,277 2,017 33,190 4,484 33,169<br />

<strong>Household</strong> size 318,013 *** 97,539 318,013 *** 98,792 306,585 *** 95,545 310,764 *** 95,568<br />

Age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals<br />

(entrepreneur) (years)<br />

4,370 10,151 4,370 10,281 1,298 9,339 2,549 9,296<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>ths<br />

doing business<br />

-809 818 -809 828 -761 806 -689 792<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Generati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> family<br />

in village<br />

107,168 83,641 107,168 84,716 110,511 78,823 110,934 78,738<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relatives<br />

in village<br />

46,844 32,868 46,844 33,290 48,340 31,638 49,922 32,272<br />

100


Appendix A<br />

Table 6: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> yearly self-employment income from livestock – GLS (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Are you member or<br />

head <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the group<br />

committee? (0/1)<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> civil<br />

servant in household<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household<br />

owned land 5 years<br />

ago<br />

Village has either pig<br />

p<strong>on</strong>d which has water<br />

throughout the year<br />

or be near river (0/1)<br />

Does village have<br />

paved road or near<br />

main road (Km 13<br />

road)? (0/1)<br />

Does village have<br />

primary school<br />

grade5? (0/1)<br />

Distance from village<br />

to main markets<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> traditi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

chicken (Gailard) per<br />

Kg<br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

1,378,544 *** 483,964 1,378,544 *** 490,183 1,413,605 *** 473,251 1,445,757 *** 479,883<br />

413,843.2 * 249,040.7 413,843.2 252,240.5 389,296 246,407 395,150 244,608<br />

0.0023 0.0029 0.0023 0.0029 0.0023 0.0027<br />

-3,014,492 2,745,199 -2,626,708 2,695,507 -2,669,113 2,678,944<br />

-654,752 684,148 -481,329 656,940 -493,312 659,751<br />

2,453,660 2,861,017 2,144,790 2,823,562 2,186,486 2,806,690<br />

-16,485 54,007 -21,839 53,026 -22,598 52,962<br />

-99.92 117 -39 99 -31.38 99.5<br />

101


Appendix A<br />

Table 6: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> yearly self-employment income from livestock – GLS (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Daily wage for<br />

c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong><br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

83 69 39 56 35 56<br />

F-statistic= 2.296443 F-statistic=2.296443 F-statistic=2.281757 F-statistic=2.388660<br />

Prob(F-statistic)=<br />

Prob(F-statistic)=<br />

Prob(F-statistic)=<br />

Prob(F-statistic)=<br />

0.002577<br />

0.002577<br />

0.003352<br />

0.002513<br />

R-squared=0.151228 R-squared=0.151228 R-squared=0.142720 R-squared=0.140397<br />

Note: the superscripts *** , ** and * denote rejecti<strong>on</strong> at 1 per cent, 5 per cent and 10 per cent critical values.<br />

Source: Author’s survey data, September 2005 and March 2006.<br />

102


Appendix A<br />

Table 7: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household yearly self-employment income from agriculture - GLS.<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

M<strong>on</strong>ths as VSG<br />

member<br />

-28,206.57 *** 9,286.57 -28,206.57 *** 9,405.89 -19,530.14 *** 7,505.15 -20,080 *** 7,381.74<br />

Does household have<br />

a VSG member?(0/1)<br />

286,830.8 * 163,582.4 286,830.8 * 165,684.2<br />

Sex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household<br />

head (female=1)<br />

-541,902 *** 108,493 -541,902 *** 109,887 -512,509 *** 107,429.6 -486,574 *** 107,728<br />

Gender <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals<br />

(entrepreneur)<br />

(female=1)<br />

72,762 129,788 72,762 131,455.9 103,554.6 128,713 74,531 127,055<br />

Maximum educati<strong>on</strong><br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals<br />

(entrepreneur) (years)<br />

-41,017.54 ** 19,608.96 -41,017.54 ** 19,860.9 -39,569.5 ** 19,779.25 -28,725.78 17,799<br />

<strong>Household</strong> size 74,184.43 *** 25,956.19 74,184.43 *** 26,289.69 74,259 *** 25,928 80,356 *** 25,993<br />

Age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals<br />

(entrepreneur) (years)<br />

6,792.35 4,806.29 6,792.35 4,868.04 5,987.76 4,768.41 7,609 * 4,585<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>ths<br />

doing business<br />

2,310.43 *** 573.26 2,310.43 *** 580.63 2,347.08 *** 579.52 2,375.99 *** 572.196<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Generati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> family<br />

in village<br />

137,675.9 ** 58,040.65 137,675.9 ** 58,786.38 138,985 ** 57,809 127,145.7 ** 56,916<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relatives<br />

in village<br />

11,847.96 21,677.13 11,847.96 21,955.64 11,319.47 22,153.05 11,529.7 22,208.8<br />

103


Appendix A<br />

Table 7: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household yearly self-employment income from agriculture – GLS (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Are you member or<br />

head <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the group<br />

committee? (0/1)<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> civil<br />

servant in household<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household<br />

owned land 5 years<br />

ago<br />

Village has either pig<br />

p<strong>on</strong>d which has water<br />

throughout the year<br />

or be near river (0/1)<br />

Does village have<br />

paved road or near<br />

main road (Km 13<br />

road)? (0/1)<br />

Does village have<br />

primary school up to<br />

grade5? (0/1)<br />

Distance from village<br />

to main markets<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> traditi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

chicken (Gailard) per<br />

Kg<br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

536,173.8 563,871 536,173.8 571,115.9 506,895 569,192.6 507,812.4 567,530<br />

82,783.2 118,974.4 82,783 120,503 107,797.9 115,761.5 158,546 105,499<br />

0.001251 *** 0.000365 0.001251 *** 0.00037 0.001144 *** 0.000367<br />

-1,348,716 5,157,754 -1,576,873 5,166,868 -1,521,957 5,156,553<br />

-1,464,704 3,444,240 -1,550,032 3,444,890 -1,536,444 3,437,276<br />

4,407,984 8,395,579 4,576,076 8,394,287 4,510,155 8,377,608<br />

-118,734 ** 59,639.55 -116,338 ** 59,163.12 -116,370 ** 59,044.5<br />

-697.26 998.98 -724.56 999.12 -720.7 996.85<br />

104


Appendix A<br />

Table 7: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household yearly self-employment income from agriculture – GLS (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Daily wage for<br />

c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong><br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

637.56 792.33 663.61 793.01 656.64 791.38<br />

F-statistic= 1.492664 F-statistic= 1.492664 F-statistic=1.537622 F-statistic=1.607735<br />

Prob(F-statistic)=<br />

Prob(F-statistic)=<br />

Prob(F-statistic)=<br />

Prob(F-statistic)=<br />

0.093412<br />

0.093412<br />

0.082866<br />

0.067655<br />

R-squared= 0.103790 R-squared= 0.103790 R-squared=0.100871 R-squared=0.099043<br />

Note: the superscripts *** , ** and * denote rejecti<strong>on</strong> at 1 per cent, 5 per cent and 10 per cent critical values.<br />

Source: Author’s survey data, September 2005 and March 2006.<br />

105


Appendix A<br />

Table 8: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household m<strong>on</strong>thly rental expenditure - GLS.<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

M<strong>on</strong>ths as VSG<br />

member<br />

138.904 ** 60.75 138.904 ** 61.53 144.28 ** 45.69 144.421 *** 45.613<br />

Does household has a<br />

VSG member?(0/1)<br />

175.558 1,355 175.558 1,372<br />

Sex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household<br />

head (female=1)<br />

2,153 1,313 2,153 1,330 2,127.22 1,358.16 2,120.69 1,352.03<br />

Gender <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals<br />

(entrepreneur)<br />

(female=1)<br />

514 1,036 513.95 1,049.55 460.495 1,024.501 367.014 1,024.34<br />

Maximum educati<strong>on</strong><br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals<br />

(entrepreneur) (years)<br />

483.38 ** 204.63 483.38 ** 207.25 488.83 ** 207.36 498.64 ** 208.93<br />

<strong>Household</strong> size -164 439.83 -164 445.48 -163.57 439.61 -155 439.1<br />

Age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals<br />

(entrepreneur) (years)<br />

-342.71 *** 124.83 -342.71 *** 126.43 -345.779 *** 123.026 -343.272 *** 121.85<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>ths<br />

doing business<br />

-9.44 ** 4.09 -9.44 ** 4.14 -9.41 ** 4.008 -9.364 ** 3.985<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Generati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> family<br />

in village<br />

8,346 *** 2,666 8,346 *** 2,700.43 8,417.66 *** 2,626.15 8,413.08 *** 2,616.92<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relatives<br />

in village<br />

-325 ** 134 -325 ** 135.42 -335.64 *** 131.47 -333.027 *** 130.446<br />

106


Appendix A<br />

Table 8: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household m<strong>on</strong>thly rental expenditure – GLS (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Are you member or<br />

head <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the group<br />

committee? (0/1)<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> civil<br />

servant in household<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household<br />

owned land 5 years<br />

ago<br />

Village has either pig<br />

p<strong>on</strong>d which has water<br />

throughout the year<br />

or be near river (0/1)<br />

Does village have<br />

paved road or near<br />

main road (Km 13<br />

road)? (0/1)<br />

Does village have<br />

primary school up to<br />

grade5? (0/1)<br />

Distance from village<br />

to main markets<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> traditi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

chicken (Gailard) per<br />

Kg<br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

-2,927 ** 1,212 -2,927 ** 1,228.03 -2,959.98 ** 1,217.54 -2,912.395 ** 1,204<br />

-1,736 ** 891 -1,736 ** 902.81 -1,734.42 ** 837.19 -1,684.74 ** 824.22<br />

0.0000027 0.0000035 0.0000027 0.0000036 0.0000027 0.0000035<br />

-46,764.79 83,436.6 -46,847.70 84,100.69 -46,844.96 83,916.4<br />

-30,659.31 55,918.17 -30,707.13 56,154.46 -30,713.54 56,031.4<br />

78,514.40 137,373.4 78,573.59 137,835.7 78,567.17 137,533.2<br />

-898.635 942.369 -897.67 932.11 -898.15 930.08<br />

-9.975 16.173 -9.984 16.258 -9.98 16.22<br />

107


Appendix A<br />

Table 8: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household m<strong>on</strong>thly rental expenditure – GLS (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Daily wage for<br />

c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong><br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

8.714 12.837 8.730 12.911 8.72 12.88<br />

F-statistic= 2.851135 F-statistic=2.851135 F-statistic=3.099860 F-statistic=3.309186<br />

Prob(F-statistic)= 0.000155 Prob(F-statistic)=<br />

Prob(F-statistic)=<br />

Prob(F-statistic)=<br />

0.000155<br />

0.000060<br />

0.000032<br />

R-squared=0.181139 R-squared=0.181139 R-squared=0.184452 R-squared=0.184518<br />

Note: the superscripts *** , ** and * denote rejecti<strong>on</strong> at 1 per cent, 5 per cent and 10 per cent critical values.<br />

Source: Author’s survey data, September 2005 and March 2006.<br />

108


Appendix A<br />

Table 9: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household m<strong>on</strong>thly educati<strong>on</strong>al expenditure - GLS.<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

M<strong>on</strong>ths as VSG<br />

member<br />

5,670.26 ** 2,768.37 5,670.26 ** 2,803.94 5,961.41 ** 2,328.64 5,975.62 ** 2,323.98<br />

Does household has a<br />

VSG member?(0/1)<br />

7,079.72 29,520.13 7,079.72 29,899.42<br />

Sex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household<br />

head (female=1)<br />

-73,346.61 49,733.75 -73,346.61 50,372.75 -71,354.07 49,884.70 -71,423.84 49,472.92<br />

Gender <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals<br />

(entrepreneur)<br />

(female=1)<br />

-21,040.16 29,964.27 -21,040.16 30,349.26 -20,434.61 28,795.59 -16,808.54 28,283.16<br />

Maximum educati<strong>on</strong><br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals<br />

(entrepreneur) (years)<br />

6,287.33 3,930.84 6,287.33 3,981.35 6,318.587 3,875.395 6,305.82 3,879.46<br />

<strong>Household</strong> size 20,529.96 *** 5,012.84 20,529.96 *** 5,077.25 20,845.82 *** 4,978.39 20,763.81 *** 4,937.83<br />

Age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals<br />

(entrepreneur) (years)<br />

1,592.31 1,142.47 1,592.31 1,157.15 1,550.24 1,129.29 1,464.46 1,108.08<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>ths<br />

doing business<br />

-210.32 ** 97.97 -210.32 ** 99.23 -201.72 ** 100.08 -207.34 ** 97.26<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Generati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> family<br />

in village<br />

-19,403.54 ** 8,778.61 -19,403.54 ** 8,891.41 -19,900.6 ** 8,926.37 -19,117.51 ** 8,493.06<br />

109


Appendix A<br />

Table 9: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household m<strong>on</strong>thly educati<strong>on</strong>al expenditure – GLS (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relatives<br />

in village<br />

Are you member or<br />

head <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the group<br />

committee? (0/1)<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> civil<br />

servant in household<br />

Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household<br />

owned land 5 years<br />

ago<br />

Village has either pig<br />

p<strong>on</strong>d which has water<br />

throughout the year<br />

or be near river (0/1)<br />

Does village have<br />

paved road or near<br />

main road (Km 13<br />

road)? (0/1)<br />

Does village have<br />

primary school up to<br />

grade5? (0/1)<br />

Distance from village<br />

to main markets<br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

-135.896 1,292.505 -135.897 1,309.112 -186.27 1,232.45 -242.82 1,241.64<br />

-19,447.98 76,584.68 -19,447.98 77,568.68 -23,655.88 7,3921.90 -24,936.75 73,712.6<br />

11,323.64 21,117.49 11,323.64 21,388.81 12,310.31 19,502.08 11,545.31 19,684.12<br />

-0.0000758 0.0000979 -0.0000758 0.0000992 -0.0000769 0.0000914<br />

-321,772.9 * 166,552.9 -328,547.7 ** 155,380.5 -327,368.3 ** 154,914.8<br />

-142,432.3 98,762.85 -144,617.5 93,385.55 -144,249.4 93,205.14<br />

408,506 * 223,862.9 413,289.4 * 214,578.9 411,673.4 * 214,079.6<br />

1,380.33 1,975.93 1,476.9 2,101.4 1,454.18 2,092.53<br />

110


Appendix A<br />

Table 9: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <strong>on</strong> household m<strong>on</strong>thly educati<strong>on</strong>al expenditure – GLS (c<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Independent<br />

variable<br />

Price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> traditi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

chicken (Gailard) per<br />

Kg<br />

Daily wage for<br />

c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong><br />

Fixed Effects model N<strong>on</strong>fixed effects model “Naïve” model “Super-naive” model<br />

Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std. Coefficient Std. Error Coefficient Std.<br />

Error<br />

Error<br />

-27.08 26.85 -28.12 25.11 -28.35 25.05<br />

16.933 21.342 17.75 19.87 17.94 19.82<br />

F-statistic= 1.670459 F-statistic=1.670459 F-statistic= 1.835944 F-statistic=1.952906<br />

Prob(F-statistic)= 0.045622 Prob(F-statistic)=<br />

Prob(F-statistic)=<br />

Prob(F-statistic)=<br />

0.045622<br />

0.024821<br />

0.017032<br />

R-squared=0.114734 R-squared=0.114734 R-squared=0.118129 R-squared=0.117802<br />

Note: the superscripts *** , ** and * denote rejecti<strong>on</strong> at 1 per cent, 5 per cent and 10 per cent critical values.<br />

Source: Author’s survey data, September 2005 and March 2006.<br />

111


Appendix B<br />

CASE STUDY<br />

SAVINGS GROUPS IN NAXAITHONG CITY<br />

This secti<strong>on</strong> discusses the savings groups in Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g city as a case study under<br />

the Women and Community’s Empowering Project (WCEP), <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the many programs<br />

which launched micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance programs in the semi-urban areas <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos. Before going to<br />

that point, we will briefly provide an overview <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> WCEP.<br />

1. Overview <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Women and Community’s Empowering Project 38<br />

1.1 Background, goal and activities<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Women and Community’s Empowering Project (WCEP), formed formally in<br />

October 2002, is cooperati<strong>on</strong> between the Lao Women’s Uni<strong>on</strong> (LWU) – a Lao<br />

Government women's organizati<strong>on</strong> – and the Community Organizati<strong>on</strong>s Development<br />

Institute: Thailand (CODI). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> project was implemented in three districts in Vientiane,<br />

the capital <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos, namely Pak Ngum, Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g and Sangth<strong>on</strong>g cities which were<br />

selected by LWU because they were the poorest districts (Asian Coaliti<strong>on</strong> for Housing<br />

Rights, 2005), for the period from October 2002 to September 2005 with budget <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

2,650,000 Baht 39 , supported by the Asian Coaliti<strong>on</strong> for Housing Rights (ACHR).<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> goal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the project is to improve quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> life for women and their families,<br />

and to support the activities for savings, credit and community fund to be a method for<br />

development. Its main activities have been:<br />

38 This secti<strong>on</strong> borrows extensively from the Report <strong>on</strong> the Implementati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Women and Community’s<br />

Empowering Project: October 2002 - September 2005, produced by the Women and Community’s<br />

Empowering Project (2005). This report which was originally written in Lao language was translated by the<br />

author.<br />

39 In 2002, average exchange rate was 42.96 Baht per <strong>on</strong>e US dollar (Bank <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Thailand, 2006).<br />

112


Appendix B<br />

• to establish the savings group and working capital fund;<br />

• to promote community activities with learning promoti<strong>on</strong>, training and<br />

processi<strong>on</strong> provisi<strong>on</strong> for community to be able to create activities for self<br />

development such as community development, community welfare<br />

provisi<strong>on</strong>, use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> natural fertilizer, sharing <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> experience;<br />

• to improve the functi<strong>on</strong>ing <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group and its branches by<br />

developing accounting system, and developing administrati<strong>on</strong> and<br />

management system for savings group, branch, district fund and central<br />

fund;<br />

• to provide advice <strong>on</strong> self-employment opportunities as well as provide<br />

training to develop marketing and other related skills<br />

1.2 Savings group<br />

1.2.1 Points <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> view<br />

Savings groups are still a new development in Laos. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are various definiti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a savings group. According to Chaleunsinh defined a savings group as:<br />

A group <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> people who share the same voluntary spirit to help each other in<br />

solving problems <strong>on</strong> financial liquidity in order to improve solidarity and upgrade<br />

the living standard <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> people within the village. Basically, the savings group is an<br />

associati<strong>on</strong> which accumulates savings <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the group’s members 40 and loans them<br />

to members who need to borrow them and charging them a loan interest rate<br />

which must be higher than the savings’ rate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> return. In additi<strong>on</strong>, some str<strong>on</strong>g<br />

savings groups also provide member support services, such as vocati<strong>on</strong>al training<br />

and establishing producti<strong>on</strong> group based <strong>on</strong> the potential <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their members<br />

(Chaleunsinh, 2004: 4-5).<br />

40 That must be equal to or higher than the minimum savings the group has established.<br />

113


Appendix B<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, according to the savings group manual <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Women and<br />

Community’s Empowering Project (n.d, 3), the savings group has to have its own<br />

organizati<strong>on</strong>al structure, which c<strong>on</strong>sists <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> group committee 41 , member, regulati<strong>on</strong>, and<br />

savings group c<strong>on</strong>sultant, received promoti<strong>on</strong> from government authority in each level and<br />

other related parties including benchmark village. More details <strong>on</strong> the organizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

structure will be discussed in following secti<strong>on</strong>s. In the next three secti<strong>on</strong>s, most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> is derived from the savings group manual <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Women and Community’s<br />

Empowering Project (n.d) 42 .<br />

1.2.2 Objectives<br />

According to the savings group manual <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Women and Community’s<br />

Empowering Project (n.d), the main objectives <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group are listed down as the<br />

following:<br />

• To reduce poverty and improve living status <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> women and their families;<br />

• To accumulate savings for village working capital fund;<br />

• To help each other and exchange knowledge and experiences <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

activities am<strong>on</strong>g members;<br />

• To strengthen women solidarity in a village;<br />

• To improve knowledge and capacity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> women such as management,<br />

accounting, credit and banking;<br />

41 Normally, the group committee at village level includes 5 people who are villagers (generally being<br />

membership <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao women uni<strong>on</strong> at village level) in the village. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y take caring every thing in the village<br />

savings group such as doing savings account, loan account, cash book, income and expenses account, and<br />

general ledger.<br />

42 This savings group manual which was originally written in Lao language was translated by the author.<br />

114


Appendix B<br />

• To sustain living status <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> members and villagers and to have good welfare<br />

step by step;<br />

• To be <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the implementati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic and social development<br />

plan which the Lao government issues in each period.<br />

1.2.3 Establishment process <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> steps for establishing a savings group are described as bellows:<br />

Step 1: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> project prop<strong>on</strong>ents meet local authorities at village level to discuss the<br />

possibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group establishment in a village. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>n, these authorities will<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sult with their villagers.<br />

Step 2: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> local authorities at village level submit a list <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the names who self<br />

select to be membership <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a savings group 43 ; to the promoter (hence may be the Lao<br />

Women Uni<strong>on</strong> at district level or the Project). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>n, a meeting is held to provide<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> about policies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the group and to set up the savings group by:<br />

• Electi<strong>on</strong> for group committee and group c<strong>on</strong>sultant;<br />

• Setting the roles for group committee, group c<strong>on</strong>sultant, and member;<br />

• Dividing the resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities for both group committee and group<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sultant;<br />

• Managing savings group with respect to the rules settled.<br />

Step 3: Group committee and group c<strong>on</strong>sultant accept the first set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings<br />

group members. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> members have to pay their membership fee and deposit m<strong>on</strong>ey with<br />

43 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> members included in the list should not be less than 20 people (Lao Women Uni<strong>on</strong>: Lao PDR and<br />

Community Organizati<strong>on</strong>s Development Institute: Thailand, n.d: 17).<br />

115


Appendix B<br />

the savings group at the deposit day which has been set out. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> group committee<br />

summarizes a financial statement after receiving the member savings.<br />

Step 4: Operati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group’s activities, such as savings and credit<br />

activities, have to follow the rules. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> group committee can receive a technical assistant<br />

from the promoter (the project) if the committee do not understand how to operate the<br />

activities, during implementati<strong>on</strong> period.<br />

Step 5: Instead <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings activities, members can think about how to create<br />

activities, for example activities for earning extra income, welfare activity, envir<strong>on</strong>ment<br />

and others, with respect to suitability and capacity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> that local area.<br />

Step 6: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> promoter <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the project, the government authority at each level and<br />

other related organizati<strong>on</strong> have to follow up and promote and support a savings group to<br />

reach the development objective <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

1.2.4 Organizati<strong>on</strong>al structure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> organizati<strong>on</strong>al structure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group c<strong>on</strong>sists <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> group committee,<br />

savings group members, group c<strong>on</strong>sultant, the promoter <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the project, the government<br />

authority and other related organizati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

A. Savings group member: A pers<strong>on</strong> who is selected and accepted to be a<br />

member by the group committee, has attributes as the following:<br />

• Self selecti<strong>on</strong> to be membership;<br />

• Harm<strong>on</strong>ious, helpful, kindness;<br />

• Acceptable and agreeable to follow the savings group regulati<strong>on</strong>s;<br />

• Rati<strong>on</strong>al and acceptable to the majority <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> others;<br />

116


Appendix B<br />

• No gender and age discriminati<strong>on</strong>;<br />

• Be a resident <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the village.<br />

B. Group committee: A pers<strong>on</strong> who received high scores from the members<br />

by electi<strong>on</strong> or voting, has attributes like:<br />

• Being a membership <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group and self selecti<strong>on</strong> to be group<br />

committee;<br />

• Trusted by others, knowledgeable, skillful and leadership experience;<br />

• Satisfied to do the job for others, h<strong>on</strong>est, faithful, patient;<br />

• Healthy<br />

• Good attitude;<br />

• No discriminati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> social class and ethic;<br />

• Accepted by majority <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> members.<br />

C. Group c<strong>on</strong>sultant: A pers<strong>on</strong> who is a representative <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the local authority<br />

at the village level or a high respected pers<strong>on</strong> in the village or a teacher, is self selected<br />

and accepted by most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the members.<br />

D. Savings group regulati<strong>on</strong>s: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> creati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> regulati<strong>on</strong> with agreement <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

members and group committee is based <strong>on</strong> particularity, suitability and capacity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a<br />

village or local. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, there are some different and similar articles in regulati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

am<strong>on</strong>g different savings groups. However, the summary <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

should have different articles as:<br />

• Membership criteria;<br />

• Minimum savings per day/per week/ per m<strong>on</strong>th.<br />

• Setting date, locati<strong>on</strong> and time <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> deposit;<br />

117


Appendix B<br />

• Setting membership fee;<br />

• Setting rules for members who save irregularly<br />

• C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for savings and dropping out from the group;<br />

• Setting loan interest rate for members such as loan for emergency sick;<br />

and normal loans (for doing rice field, crop plant, livestock, educati<strong>on</strong><br />

and other);<br />

• Setting c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for member borrowing such as c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> and right<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> borrowing; and term <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loan repayment;<br />

• Allocating benefit from total revenue at the year ended such as:<br />

o Dividend payment to members 44 (based <strong>on</strong> calculati<strong>on</strong> rate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

member deposit or share ratio);<br />

o Administrati<strong>on</strong> budget such as wage for group committee and<br />

group c<strong>on</strong>sultant; savings group expenditure which is savings<br />

group reserve;<br />

o Village development fund;<br />

o <strong>Welfare</strong> fund;<br />

o Other fund which is beneficial to village, agreed by member and<br />

group committee;<br />

• Setting aging or period <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> group committee and group c<strong>on</strong>sultant;<br />

• Regulati<strong>on</strong> can be improved and changed with respect to agreement<br />

and suitability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> most members.<br />

44 Normally, dividend paid to the member is come from 70% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>it and the rest <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>it (30%) is allocated to different categories <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fund and reserve (for particular rate is depended <strong>on</strong><br />

practice <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> each savings group), according to author’s survey data (September, 2005).<br />

118


Appendix B<br />

1.2.5 Results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the project implementati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> savings group<br />

During the period <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the project, savings groups have been established in number<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> villages in three target districts. It can be seen from table 1 that there were many<br />

villages demanding to voluntarily establish a savings group in own village. As a result,<br />

there were 24 more savings groups than the number planned. Table 2 shows that about<br />

84% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the villages in the three pilot districts have their own savings groups. It means<br />

that savings groups have good outreach to provide financial services for villagers.<br />

Table 1: Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings groups established during the period from<br />

October 2002 to September 2005<br />

Areas Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Savings Group<br />

Planned number Actual number Variati<strong>on</strong><br />

Pak Ngum district 17 25 8<br />

Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g district 31 37 6<br />

Sangth<strong>on</strong>g district 17 27 10<br />

Total 65 89 24<br />

Source: Women and Community’s Empowering Project (2005: 42)<br />

Table 2: Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group in three districts compared to number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Districts Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Villages<br />

villages as the statistic <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> July 2005<br />

Number 45 Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

member<br />

119<br />

Savings Groups<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

families<br />

Deposit<br />

balance in<br />

Kip<br />

Pak Ngum district 53 55 5,201 3,963 3,616,44,500<br />

Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g district 56 38 6,128 3,877 1,674,802,000<br />

Sangth<strong>on</strong>g district 37 30 2,704 2,164 734,514,500<br />

Total 146 123 14,033 10,004 6,025,761,000<br />

Source: Women and Community’s Empowering Project (2005: 43)<br />

45 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number in this column is higher than the figures in third column <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> table 1 because it included the<br />

number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings groups implemented before October 2002 as Pak Ngum district with 30 savings groups,<br />

Naxayth<strong>on</strong>g district with <strong>on</strong>e savings group, and Saength<strong>on</strong>g district with three savings groups (Women<br />

and Community’s Empowering Project, 2005).


Appendix B<br />

Savings groups in the three districts provide different kinds <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loans to their<br />

members. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> largest loan balance is loans for planting rice field in all three districts,<br />

followed by credit for trade and other services.<br />

Table 3: Loan balance for the savings groups in each district as April 2005<br />

No. Types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

loan<br />

Pak Ngum district Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g district Sangth<strong>on</strong>g district<br />

No. <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Loan balance No. <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Loan No. <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Loan balance<br />

borrowers<br />

borrowers balance borrowers<br />

1 Crop plant 230 314,638,000 151 94,700,000 183 141,550,000<br />

2 Textile 46 387 212,360,000 27 9,080,000 420 253,260,000<br />

3 Trade and<br />

other<br />

services<br />

273 1,304,487,000 144 174,900,000 567 456,380,000<br />

4 Emergency<br />

sick<br />

327 181,916,000 - - - -<br />

5 Sick - - 95 32,800,000 63 30,750,000<br />

6 Emergency - - 34 76,830,000 75 58,340,000<br />

7 Rice field<br />

planting<br />

1,747 1,570,942,300 700 260,749,500 1,016 619,937,000<br />

Total 2,964 3,584,343,300 1,151 649,059,500 2,324 1,560,217,000<br />

Note: “-” means no balance.<br />

Source: Women and Community’s Empowering Project (2005: 45-46)<br />

However, this paper will focus <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong> savings groups in Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g district as<br />

the case study due to limitati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> time and budget. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> following secti<strong>on</strong> will discuss<br />

more details about the case study.<br />

2. Savings groups in Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g district<br />

2.1 Background<br />

Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g city, located in the area <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Vientiane, the capital <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Laos, is about 16<br />

Km from the capital. A total <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 56 villages in Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g district are divided to six z<strong>on</strong>es.<br />

46<br />

In Naxayth<strong>on</strong>g district, this type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loan is provided borrowers, who do textile <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao skirt, called Tam<br />

Hook.<br />

120


Appendix B<br />

Its populati<strong>on</strong> is 57,129 people c<strong>on</strong>sisting <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 28,761 females and there are 10,378 families<br />

(Women and Community’s Empowering Project, 2005: 40-41).<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> main ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities in this district are planting rice fields, crop plants,<br />

livestock, textile and trade. According to the Women and Community’s Empowering<br />

Project (2005: 41), the living status <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> populati<strong>on</strong> in this district was poor before the<br />

establishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group. This could be seen from low income levels, lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

capital for producti<strong>on</strong>, and lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> finance for smoothing c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> and other activities.<br />

This led to the selling <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Green Rice 47 and borrowing m<strong>on</strong>ey from the informal sector<br />

such as m<strong>on</strong>ey lenders at high m<strong>on</strong>thly interest rates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 10 percent to 30 percent. For<br />

example, in the 38 villages which have savings groups, 423 families sell green rice; 1,202<br />

families obtained a loan from m<strong>on</strong>ey lender; and 57 families were classified as being <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a<br />

poor status before the establishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings groups. In additi<strong>on</strong>, in the absence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

the savings group, the educati<strong>on</strong> level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the people was limited due to a lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> learning<br />

opportunities, especially for women and lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> knowledge and ability for management<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> different activities.<br />

In June 2001, a savings group was implemented in Naxayth<strong>on</strong>g district. Now,<br />

there are 38 village savings groups available in four z<strong>on</strong>es <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this district as shown in the<br />

table 2.<br />

2.2 Financial services <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings groups in Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g District<br />

Savings groups provided some basic financial services such as credit and savings<br />

to their members. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> following secti<strong>on</strong> discusses the findings <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the survey c<strong>on</strong>ducted in<br />

47 As Chanleunsinh (2004:8) defined as, “Green rice selling or Khai Khao Khiew means farmers sell rice at<br />

a discounted price, which is evaluated by the middleman or the traders, before it is harvested. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

traders/middle men then come to take the rice after it is harvested”.<br />

121


Appendix B<br />

six <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these villages. Six villages which the author did field survey in September 2005<br />

and March 2006.<br />

2.2.1 Source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fund<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> two main sources <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> funds for running savings group are internal funds and<br />

external funds 48 . Internal funds come from deposit amounts from member <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings<br />

group (see table 4). At beginning <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> each m<strong>on</strong>th, normally at the first day <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the m<strong>on</strong>th,<br />

the members have to deposit m<strong>on</strong>ey to savings groups <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> at least the minimum required<br />

amount 49 which is <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the membership rules. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is no interest paid <strong>on</strong> such deposits<br />

but members receive dividends every twelve m<strong>on</strong>ths 50 . 70 per cent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the savings group<br />

pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>it is paid to each member as a dividend. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> dividend payment to each member is<br />

based <strong>on</strong> share ratio or proporti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> deposit <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> each member to total deposit balance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

whole savings group. This implies that deposit amount per time from members who<br />

require more dividend tends to be increased every m<strong>on</strong>th.<br />

External funds are a s<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>t loan from the central funds which are managed by the<br />

management committee <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the project. This loan is lent to a savings group the funds <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

which are not sufficient fund for borrowers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> process <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> making a s<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>t loan request<br />

48<br />

Besides the two main sources <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fund, interest income from loan to members is <strong>on</strong>e source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fund for<br />

savings group.<br />

49<br />

Minimum deposit amount is normally 5,000 Kip per m<strong>on</strong>th or equivalent to 0.46US dollar as exchange<br />

rate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 10,890 Kip per a dollar in September 2005, according to six savings groups <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this case study. Until<br />

September 2005, there has been no limitati<strong>on</strong> for maximum deposit amount in those six savings group.<br />

However, there is limitati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> maximum deposit, up to <strong>on</strong>e milli<strong>on</strong> kip per time, in case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group<br />

in Nakountay village at the time <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> follow up survey <strong>on</strong> 2 nd March 2006.<br />

50<br />

(a)If members withdraw deposit before dividend payment date, they will not receive any dividend from<br />

their deposit accumulati<strong>on</strong>. (b) If they withdraw at dividend payment date, they will still get dividend from<br />

their deposit, but if they need a sequent loan, they cannot withdraw their deposit. (c) <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y can withdraw<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly at the day <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> withdrawal, not the deposit day, (<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> deposit day is the day to make a plan to request for<br />

withdrawal).<br />

122


Appendix B<br />

starts with members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group making borrowing plans to their savings groups.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> plans are submitted to the committee at z<strong>on</strong>e level, through the fund committee at<br />

district level to the central fund. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> central fund committee issues the s<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>t loan to the<br />

fund committee at district level. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>n, the committee at district level will lend to the<br />

members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> different groups who make borrowing plans with approval <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fund<br />

committee at district level (Women and Community’s Empowering Project, 2005: 63-64).<br />

Table 4: Credit balance and source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fund in six savings groups as<br />

September 2005<br />

Date <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

Members Loan balance<br />

Source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fund as<br />

September 2005<br />

savings<br />

in as September<br />

External<br />

group Populati<strong>on</strong> savings 2005 Internal fund fund<br />

No. Villages established in village group<br />

Kip<br />

Kip Kip<br />

1 Nakountay 01-Oct-02 1,089 300 167,000,000 158,148,500 -<br />

2 Huannamyene 12-Jun-03 1,710 338 136,200,000 109,031,000 -<br />

3 D<strong>on</strong>gluang 01-Apr-04 1,048 153 74,700,000 56,499,000 6,000,000<br />

4 Ph<strong>on</strong>ekeo 15-Jun-05 532 145 13,112,000 11,967,000 11,000,000<br />

5 Ph<strong>on</strong>esavanh 01-Jun-05 680 74 650,000 650,000 -<br />

6 Sisavard 10-Aug-05 393 121 1,200,000 1,120,000 -<br />

Source: Author’s survey data, September 2005 and March 2006.<br />

In the survey sample, there were two savings groups which had external funds.<br />

One is a savings group in D<strong>on</strong>gluang village which received a s<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>t loan from the fund<br />

committee <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g district amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> six milli<strong>on</strong>s Kip with <strong>on</strong>e year term <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loan<br />

and 2% interest rate per m<strong>on</strong>th, <strong>on</strong> 5 th August 2005. However, the savings group could<br />

123


Appendix B<br />

repay this loan by three m<strong>on</strong>ths later. A savings group in Ph<strong>on</strong>ekeo village was another<br />

<strong>on</strong>e which obtained s<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>t loan from the fund committee <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g city. On the 1 st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

August, 2005, this savings group borrowed from the fund committee <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g city<br />

the amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 11 milli<strong>on</strong> Kip with a <strong>on</strong>e year term <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the loan and 3% interest rate per<br />

m<strong>on</strong>th. At the time <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> follow up survey in this village, 3rd March 2006, this loan was yet<br />

not repaid.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, as table 4 shows four savings groups are dependent <strong>on</strong> internal funds<br />

(member deposit) in order to lend to their members. This implies that most savings<br />

groups in Laos are much based <strong>on</strong> savings mobilizati<strong>on</strong> for lending to their members<br />

rather than s<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>t loans or external funds for the project. This is in c<strong>on</strong>trast to the village<br />

bank system in Northeast Thailand <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the study by Coleman (1999). Even though, this<br />

approach was promoted by Thai NGO, Community Organizati<strong>on</strong>s Development Institute:<br />

Thailand (CODI) which follow the “Village Bank” group lending methodology <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

Foundati<strong>on</strong> for Internati<strong>on</strong>al Community Assistance (FINCA) 51 (Chaleunsinh, 2004: 7).<br />

This result is c<strong>on</strong>sistent with Chaleunshinh that:<br />

“Savings group” operati<strong>on</strong> in Lao PDR, especially in Vientiane Capital, is quite<br />

different from the “Village Bank” system in Northeast Thailand, due to the fact<br />

that most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the village savings groups in Laos are currently based <strong>on</strong> m<strong>on</strong>ey<br />

mobilized within their villages or internal funds rather than from s<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>t loans from a<br />

project. However, this approach was promoted by the Thai NGOs, Foundati<strong>on</strong> for<br />

Integrated Agricultural Management: FIAM, and Community Organizati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Development Institute: Thailand or CODI, starting in 1997. Both organizati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

follow the “Village Bank” group lending methodology <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Foundati<strong>on</strong> for<br />

Internati<strong>on</strong>al Community Assistance (Chaleunsinh, 2004:7).<br />

51 Please refer to Ledgerwood (1999: 85) for more explanati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Village Bank.<br />

124


Appendix B<br />

2.2.2 Credit<br />

Savings groups lend m<strong>on</strong>ey to their members <strong>on</strong> a m<strong>on</strong>thly basis. Normally, the<br />

borrowing day is the day after deposit day. Members who require the loans fill the loan<br />

request form and submit it at the deposit day. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> group committee collects all the<br />

request forms 52 and summaries the amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loan requested. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y then check how much<br />

m<strong>on</strong>ey the group has at that time 53 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group provides different kinds <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loan as<br />

shown in table 3. In the six savings groups <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this sample, loan size is range from 100,000<br />

Kip to 5,000,000 Kip with a 5% interest rate per m<strong>on</strong>th 54 and 3 to 6 m<strong>on</strong>ths term <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loan 55 .<br />

Limitati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loan size is dependent <strong>on</strong> the practices <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> each savings groups. For example,<br />

in the case study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the six savings groups, the groups in D<strong>on</strong>gluang, Huannamyene and<br />

Ph<strong>on</strong>esavanh villages have a minimum loan size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 100,000 Kip while other three savings<br />

groups have not settled for that. For maximum loan size, savings groups in Nakountay,<br />

D<strong>on</strong>gluang and Ph<strong>on</strong>esavanh villages have settled at amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 5 milli<strong>on</strong> Kip, <strong>on</strong>e<br />

milli<strong>on</strong> Kip and 300,000Kip respectively, whereas the rest three savings groups have not<br />

settled for that but they c<strong>on</strong>sider the loan size depending <strong>on</strong> the borrowing request and<br />

how much the group have m<strong>on</strong>ey for (deposit amount).<br />

52<br />

Generally, borrowing c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s are settled in different way am<strong>on</strong>g savings groups. In case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings<br />

group in Nakountay village, some c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for member borrowing are: (1) members have to have deposit<br />

amount with the group for guarantee; (2) If they borrow at 500,000kip, TV or freeze can be collateral; if<br />

they borrow amount more than 3,000,000kip, a land certificate can be collateral but it is also depended <strong>on</strong><br />

how much volume <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their deposit with the group; (3) if member has no any things to be guarantee, friends<br />

can be guarantor; (4) If a wife borrows, her husband has to be guarantor and vice versa.<br />

53<br />

Normally, savings group does not keep any m<strong>on</strong>ey balance with the group after receiving deposit from<br />

members, then the day after, all m<strong>on</strong>ey has to lend out to members depending <strong>on</strong> their request and<br />

borrowing c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s. In case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> deposit balance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the group remaining at 1 milli<strong>on</strong> Kip, the group<br />

committee will deposit that balance to bank such as Agricultural Promoti<strong>on</strong> Bank, an example <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings<br />

group in Nakountay village.<br />

54<br />

Sometimes, interest rate per m<strong>on</strong>th is 3%, an example <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group at Nakountay village, it is<br />

depended <strong>on</strong> what kinds <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loan.<br />

55<br />

Three new village savings groups have 3 m<strong>on</strong>ths term <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loan while three old village savings group<br />

practice <strong>on</strong> 6 m<strong>on</strong>ths term <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loan during the survey time. For example, savings group in Nakountay village,<br />

term <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loan was 3 m<strong>on</strong>ths for the period from year 2002 to 2004, but since 2 March 2005, term <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> loan has<br />

been 6 m<strong>on</strong>ths.<br />

125


Appendix B<br />

3. Other financial service providers in Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g district<br />

According to the author’s survey in September 2005, some financial service<br />

providers, apart from the savings group, provide basic financial services, mainly credit<br />

and deposits in the survey area. For credit access, 12% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> sample survey could obtain a<br />

loan from financial providers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Agricultural Promoti<strong>on</strong> Bank (APB) was the first<br />

financial provider at 6%, followed by m<strong>on</strong>ey lender at 4%, while other micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance<br />

providers covered <strong>on</strong>ly by 1% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> sample survey (see table 5). It is interesting that 17% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

the c<strong>on</strong>trol group had access to credit from other financial providers. Of that, APB was<br />

the most dominant financial provider at 12%.<br />

In terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> deposit service, about 9% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> those surveyed in the sample deposited<br />

with other financial providers. APB and other micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance providers covered by 4% per<br />

each while the 2% was covered by m<strong>on</strong>ey rotating (see table 6). For c<strong>on</strong>trol group sample,<br />

8% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its sample could access to financial providers which APB and other micr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inance<br />

providers shared that percent by half per each.<br />

126


Appendix B<br />

Table 5: Loan balance at different sources <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> finance for sample survey in six<br />

villages as September 2005<br />

Mean by group: Sources <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> credit:<br />

Other<br />

APB MFIs b)<br />

M<strong>on</strong>ey<br />

Relative<br />

&<br />

lender friend Total<br />

Interest rate per day (%):<br />

All sample (n=251):<br />

0.02 - 0.17 0.167 - 0.2 0.7 - 1 0 - 10<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> borrowers 0.06 0.01 0.04 0.02 0.12 a)<br />

Loan amount (Kip)<br />

Member (n=183):<br />

40,035,438 41,833 39,982 21,978 40,139,231<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> borrowers 0.07 0.02 0.04 0.03 0.15<br />

Loan amount (Kip)<br />

Treatment group(n=131):<br />

54,851,885 57,377 51,833 30,145 54,991,240<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> borrowers 0.05 0.02 0.04 0.03 0.14<br />

Loan amount (Kip)<br />

C<strong>on</strong>trol group (n=52):<br />

231,870 80,153 10,687 41,729 364,439<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> borrowers 0.12 - 0.04 0.02 0.17<br />

Loan amount (Kip) 192,452,308<br />

N<strong>on</strong>member (n=68):<br />

- 155,489 962 193,000,000<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> borrowers 0.03 - 0.03 - 0.06<br />

Loan amount (Kip) 161,765 - 8,088 - 169,853<br />

Note: a) One pers<strong>on</strong> could access to credit in both APB and relative &friends.<br />

b) This c<strong>on</strong>sists <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings group <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lao Women Uni<strong>on</strong> at Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g city, Rural<br />

Development Cooperative Naxaith<strong>on</strong>g and others.<br />

Source: Author’s survey data, September 2005.<br />

127


Appendix B<br />

Table 6: Deposit balance at different instituti<strong>on</strong>s as September 2005<br />

Mean by group: Deposit balance at different instituti<strong>on</strong>s:<br />

Other<br />

APB MFIs M<strong>on</strong>ey rotating Total<br />

Interest rate per year (%): 8 - 24 0 - 3<br />

All sample (n=251):<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> depositors 0.04 0.04 0.02 0.09 a)<br />

Deposit balance (Kip) 32,207 12,530 1,801 46,538<br />

Member (n=183):<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> depositors 0.05 0.05 0.02 0.12<br />

Deposit balance (Kip) 30,514 17,186 2,377 50,077<br />

Treatment group (n=131):<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> depositors 0.05 0.06 0.02 0.14<br />

Deposit balance (Kip) 40,840 22,634 3,321 66,794<br />

C<strong>on</strong>trol group (n=52):<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> depositors 0.04 0.04 0.08<br />

Deposit balance (Kip) 4,500 3,462 7,962<br />

N<strong>on</strong>member (n=68):<br />

Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> depositors 0.01 0.01 0.01<br />

Deposit balance (Kip) 36,765 250 37,015<br />

Note: a) One pers<strong>on</strong> deposited with both APB and M<strong>on</strong>ey rotating<br />

Source: Author’s survey data, September 2005.<br />

128

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!