16.08.2013 Views

Emerging-Market Multinational Enterprises in Developed Markets:

Emerging-Market Multinational Enterprises in Developed Markets:

Emerging-Market Multinational Enterprises in Developed Markets:

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Emerg<strong>in</strong>g</strong>-<strong>Market</strong> <strong>Mult<strong>in</strong>ational</strong> <strong>Enterprises</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Developed</strong> <strong>Market</strong>s:<br />

Explor<strong>in</strong>g Reverse Spillover Effects on Parent Firms<br />

Victor Zitian Chen 1<br />

, J<strong>in</strong>g Li, Daniel M. Shapiro<br />

Jack Aust<strong>in</strong> Centre for Asia Pacific Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Studies<br />

Segal Graduate School of Bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

Beedie School of Bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

Simon Fraser University<br />

500 Granville Street, Vancouver<br />

BC V6C 1W6, Canada<br />

1 Correspondence author. Contact <strong>in</strong>formation: zca4@sfu.ca.


<strong>Emerg<strong>in</strong>g</strong>-<strong>Market</strong> <strong>Mult<strong>in</strong>ational</strong> <strong>Enterprises</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Developed</strong> <strong>Market</strong>s:<br />

Explor<strong>in</strong>g Reverse Spillover Effects on Parent Firms<br />

ABSTRACT<br />

This study exam<strong>in</strong>es whether and to what extent emerg<strong>in</strong>g-market mult<strong>in</strong>ational<br />

enterprises (EM MNEs) can use outward FDI <strong>in</strong> a developed market to capture<br />

knowledge spillovers so as to improve their technological capabilities at home. We<br />

refer to this as a “reverse spillover” effect on parent firms, and develop it based on<br />

the knowledge-seek<strong>in</strong>g motive for FDI by EM MNEs. Extend<strong>in</strong>g previous studies<br />

that have identified the knowledge-seek<strong>in</strong>g motive and have also provided some<br />

evidence for its validity, our study focuses on the effects of such FDI on<br />

technological capabilities of EM MNEs at home. Us<strong>in</strong>g a panel dataset of 493 EM<br />

MNEs over the period 2000-2008, and controll<strong>in</strong>g for possible endogeneity, we f<strong>in</strong>d<br />

evidence support<strong>in</strong>g the reverse spillover effect: EM MNEs that have subsidiaries <strong>in</strong><br />

host developed markets richer <strong>in</strong> technological resources (measured by R&D<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments and R&D employment) exhibit stronger technological capabilities at<br />

home. We discuss the implications of our study for research and practice related to<br />

the <strong>in</strong>ternationalization of EM MNEs.<br />

Key Words: emerg<strong>in</strong>g market, developed market, mult<strong>in</strong>ational enterprise, outward<br />

FDI, R&D, knowledge spillover, technology transfer<br />

JEL Codes: F21, F23, G11, G34, M16, O19, O31, O32, O33, O34, Y40<br />

1


<strong>Emerg<strong>in</strong>g</strong>-<strong>Market</strong> <strong>Mult<strong>in</strong>ational</strong> <strong>Enterprises</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Developed</strong> <strong>Market</strong>s:<br />

Explor<strong>in</strong>g Reverse Spillover Effects on Parent Firms<br />

INTRODUCTION<br />

The penetration of emerg<strong>in</strong>g market mult<strong>in</strong>ational enterprises (EM MNEs) <strong>in</strong>to developed<br />

markets (DMs) through outward foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestments (OFDI) is a significant but relatively<br />

understudied phenomenon (e.g., Bertoni, Elia, and Rabbiosi, 2008; Buckley, Elia, and Kafouros, 2010;<br />

Yamakawa, Peng, and Deeds, 2008). An important motivation for such OFDI is to access advanced<br />

knowledge and capabilities available <strong>in</strong> DMs and to utilize them to improve the technological and<br />

<strong>in</strong>novative capabilities of the parent companies <strong>in</strong> emerg<strong>in</strong>g markets (Mak<strong>in</strong>o, Lau, and Yeh, 2002;<br />

Mathews and Zander, 2007; Luo and Tung, 2007; Rui and Yip, 2008; Deng, 2009). This “knowledge<br />

seek<strong>in</strong>g” motivation of EM MNEs has been supported by recent studies that have <strong>in</strong>vestigated EM<br />

MNEs’ entry decisions (e.g., location choice) as a function of technological endowments <strong>in</strong> host<br />

markets (Bertoni et al., 2008; Buckley, Clegg, Cross, Liu, Voss, and Zheng, 2007). While it is critical<br />

to <strong>in</strong>vestigate the impact of knowledge seek<strong>in</strong>g on EM MNEs’ entry decisions, it is equally important<br />

to understand whether <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> DMs have actually generated positive spillover effects that<br />

augment technological capabilities of EM MNEs at home. To our knowledge, however, no studies<br />

have <strong>in</strong>vestigated the latter topic. Our study aims to fill this literature gap.<br />

Specifically, we hypothesize that OFDI <strong>in</strong> DMs will positively affect technological capabilities<br />

of EM MNE parent firms, which we refer to as reverse spillover effects. Positive reverse spillover<br />

effects are realized through knowledge spillovers to EM subsidiaries <strong>in</strong> a developed market and the<br />

knowledge transfer from these subsidiaries to their parents <strong>in</strong> EMs. The reverse spillover effect<br />

contrasts with the more conventional approach to spillover benefits for firms <strong>in</strong> emerg<strong>in</strong>g markets<br />

which focuses on spillovers from DM MNEs <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> emerg<strong>in</strong>g markets to host market firms (for<br />

reviews, see Globerman and Chen, 2010, and Meyer and S<strong>in</strong>ani, 2009).<br />

Empirically, we utilize a panel dataset consist<strong>in</strong>g of 493 MNEs from 20 different EMs between<br />

2000 and 2008. We use R&D expenditures of the parent firm <strong>in</strong> the home market to measure its<br />

technological capabilities. We employ three measures (R&D <strong>in</strong>vestment, R&D employment, and<br />

number of patents) to capture the level of technological resources <strong>in</strong> a host market, all adjusted for<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry. Our primary focus is on the relationship between parent-firm R&D expenditures and the level<br />

2


of technological resources <strong>in</strong> the host market. Because it is possible that technology flows from the<br />

parent firm at home to the host market, we are careful to control for possible endogeneity <strong>in</strong> our<br />

empirical work. We use <strong>in</strong>strumental variable methods and Hausman tests to ensure that host-market<br />

technological measures are exogenous. Us<strong>in</strong>g panel Tobit regressions, we f<strong>in</strong>d evidence support<strong>in</strong>g our<br />

ma<strong>in</strong> prediction that technological resources related to R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments and R&D employment <strong>in</strong> a<br />

host market-<strong>in</strong>dustry have a significant, positive effect on the R&D expenditures of the EM parent<br />

companies that have <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> the host market-<strong>in</strong>dustry.<br />

Our study contributes to the FDI literature <strong>in</strong> at least two important aspects. First, our study<br />

contributes to the literature that <strong>in</strong>vestigates FDI spillover effects on the technological capabilities of<br />

EM firms. The majority of this literature has focused on spillover effects of <strong>in</strong>ward FDI <strong>in</strong> EMs on<br />

technological improvement of firms <strong>in</strong> the host markets (e.g., Aitken and Harrison, 1999; Girma, Gong,<br />

and Görg, 2009; Globerman, 1979; Haddad and Harrison, 1993; Li, Chen, and Shapiro, 2010; Zhang,<br />

Li, Li, and Zhou, 2010; for a review, see Meyer and S<strong>in</strong>ani, 2009). This literature has suggested that<br />

<strong>in</strong>ward FDI tends to generate knowledge spillovers that benefit local firms <strong>in</strong> EMs as host markets by<br />

enhanc<strong>in</strong>g their technological capabilities (Cantwell, 1989; Caves, 1996). Although there have been<br />

studies of reverse spillover effects on foreign subsidiaries (Driffield and Love, 2003), the FDI<br />

literature has yet to exam<strong>in</strong>e the potential reverse capability benefits of OFDI on the EM MNE parent<br />

(Globerman and Chen, 2010; Meyer and S<strong>in</strong>ani, 2009).<br />

Second, our study contributes to the literature on OFDI of EM MNEs. Previous studies have<br />

largely concentrated on the <strong>in</strong>fluence of technological resources <strong>in</strong> a host market on entry-related<br />

decisions (Bertoni et al., 2008; Buckley et al., 2007). For <strong>in</strong>stance, Bertoni et al. (2008) suggested that<br />

firms from Brazil, Russia, India, and Ch<strong>in</strong>a use horizontal acquisitions <strong>in</strong> developed markets to access<br />

technological resources. Buckley et al. (2007) found that Ch<strong>in</strong>ese MNEs are more likely to locate <strong>in</strong> a<br />

foreign market that has rich technological endowments. Our study is among the first attempts to<br />

exam<strong>in</strong>e the post-entry consequences of EM MNEs’ <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> DMs.<br />

We adopt three alternative measures for host-market technological resources, and f<strong>in</strong>d that EM<br />

MNEs that have subsidiaries <strong>in</strong> host markets that are rich <strong>in</strong> R&D-based resources tend to benefit<br />

significantly from knowledge spillovers and knowledge transfer to the parent. However, EM MNEs<br />

that have subsidiaries <strong>in</strong> patent-rich host markets do not benefit <strong>in</strong> the same way. These results suggest<br />

more nuanced conclusions regard<strong>in</strong>g reverse spillovers. Specifically we argue that R&D-related<br />

3


knowledge embedded <strong>in</strong> researchers, local universities and bus<strong>in</strong>ess networks is relatively tacit and<br />

location bound and can therefore be accessed only through locational choices. Patents, on the other<br />

hand, are not only codified and tradable but can also be accessed via market transactions (e.g., licenses)<br />

by EM MNEs even when they have no presence <strong>in</strong> the host markets where the patents are <strong>in</strong>vented.<br />

The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. We review the literature and develop our ma<strong>in</strong><br />

hypothesis <strong>in</strong> section two, discuss empirical methods <strong>in</strong> section three, and present the results <strong>in</strong> section<br />

four. We conclude the study by discuss<strong>in</strong>g its implications and potential future extensions.<br />

THEORY AND HYPOTHESIS DEVELOPMENT<br />

Knowledge Seek<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>Emerg<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Market</strong> Firms <strong>in</strong> <strong>Developed</strong> <strong>Market</strong>s<br />

Knowledge seek<strong>in</strong>g FDI is geared less to exploit<strong>in</strong>g an exist<strong>in</strong>g ownership advantage of an<br />

MNE, and more to augment<strong>in</strong>g firm specific advantages by the acquisition of new knowledge<br />

(Cantwell, 1989; Dunn<strong>in</strong>g, 1981, 2001; Wesson, 1999). Consistent with the knowledge seek<strong>in</strong>g<br />

motivation, research studies have found that firms from technologically lagg<strong>in</strong>g countries tend to<br />

<strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> countries with stronger technological positions (Kogut and Chang, 1991; Kuemmerle, 1999;<br />

Florida, 1997; Serapio and Dalton, 1999). For <strong>in</strong>stance, Kogut and Chang (1991) observed that<br />

Japanese firms entered <strong>in</strong>dustries <strong>in</strong> the United States that have stronger R&D capabilities than <strong>in</strong><br />

Japan. Similarly, Kuemmerle (1999) found that MNEs are <strong>in</strong>cl<strong>in</strong>ed to establish R&D laboratories <strong>in</strong> a<br />

host market when the country commits more to R&D activities and offers more qualified human<br />

resources than the MNE’s home market.<br />

Knowledge seek<strong>in</strong>g through OFDI is particularly emphasized by the literature on<br />

<strong>in</strong>ternationalization of firms from emerg<strong>in</strong>g and develop<strong>in</strong>g markets. This literature suggests that firms<br />

use <strong>in</strong>ternational expansion as a “spr<strong>in</strong>gboard” to access knowledge overseas, to compensate for their<br />

competitive weaknesses, and to overcome their latecomer disadvantages (Luo and Tung, 2007;<br />

Mak<strong>in</strong>o et al., 2002; Mathews, 2002, 2006; Child and Rodrigues, 2005). Mathews (2006) and<br />

Mathews and Zander (2007), for <strong>in</strong>stance, argued that Asian EM MNEs should build l<strong>in</strong>kages with<br />

DM companies, leverage their own resource advantages, and ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> strong learn<strong>in</strong>g motives when<br />

enter<strong>in</strong>g DMs. Empirically, Mak<strong>in</strong>o et al. (2002) found evidence that firms from Taiwan engage <strong>in</strong> FDI<br />

not only when they possess firm-specific advantages for asset exploitation but also when they <strong>in</strong>tend to<br />

4


seek technology-based resources and skills that are not available <strong>in</strong> their home market. Similarly,<br />

Bertoni et al. (2008) and Buckley et al. (2007) found evidences to support the prediction that EM<br />

MNEs tend to choose host markets rich <strong>in</strong> technology.<br />

The ultimate objective for EM MNEs’ knowledge-seek<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> DMs is to improve<br />

their technological capabilities <strong>in</strong> their home market (e.g., Child and Rodrigues, 2005). Research<br />

studies have shown that EM MNEs strive to reduce reliance on foreign technologies, to develop<br />

“<strong>in</strong>digenous knowledge” (Aubert, 2004: 13), and to develop “<strong>in</strong>digenous <strong>in</strong>novation” (Fu, Pietrobelli,<br />

and Soete, 2010: 1). The determ<strong>in</strong>ation of EM MNEs to improve <strong>in</strong>digenous <strong>in</strong>novation has also been<br />

re<strong>in</strong>forced by policy support by home-market governments; governments <strong>in</strong> EMs have adopted such<br />

favorable policies as tax <strong>in</strong>centives and direct f<strong>in</strong>ancial assistance to encourage and reward <strong>in</strong>digenous<br />

technological efforts (e.g., Crist<strong>in</strong>a and Vang, 2006; Peng, 2010).<br />

Given the knowledge-seek<strong>in</strong>g motive of EM MNEs <strong>in</strong> developed markets, a natural question is<br />

whether and how EM MNEs can <strong>in</strong>deed augment their technological capabilities through OFDI <strong>in</strong><br />

DMs. We explore next the theoretical mechanisms through which OFDI <strong>in</strong> DMs can possibly affect<br />

technological capabilities of the parent companies of EM MNEs at home.<br />

Knowledge Spillovers on Subsidiaries of <strong>Emerg<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Market</strong> Firms <strong>in</strong> <strong>Developed</strong> <strong>Market</strong>s<br />

Follow<strong>in</strong>g the knowledge spillover literature, we suggest that by present<strong>in</strong>g themselves <strong>in</strong> DMs,<br />

subsidiaries of EM MNEs can benefit from knowledge spillovers (e.g., technology and knowhow<br />

spillovers) from local companies <strong>in</strong> the host markets (e.g., Atk<strong>in</strong>son and Stiglitz, 1969; Globerman,<br />

1979; Koizumi and Kopecky, 1977). The knowledge spillover literature <strong>in</strong>dicates that knowledge is<br />

spatially bounded <strong>in</strong> nature, and knowledge spillovers are therefore also spatially bounded. This is<br />

because most technology-generat<strong>in</strong>g facilities and resources such as labs, equipment, and researchers<br />

are location-specific, and R&D workers’ communications and turnovers are accommodated by local<br />

networks (Jaffe, Trajtenberg, and Henderson, 1993; Griliches, 1984, 1992; Globerman, Shapiro, and<br />

V<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g, 2005). Therefore, to benefit from knowledge spillovers, an EM MNE needs to have a physical<br />

presence <strong>in</strong> these locations and embed itself <strong>in</strong> local networks that are rich <strong>in</strong> technological resources<br />

(Almeida and Kogut, 1999).<br />

Specifically, knowledge can be spilled over to subsidiaries of EM MNEs through several<br />

channels. First, the subsidiaries can acquire knowledge by participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> local supply cha<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> a<br />

5


developed market. Studies have shown that knowledge spillovers are associated with purchases and<br />

usage of high-technology <strong>in</strong>termediate products made by local suppliers (Javorcik, 2004). Second, the<br />

subsidiaries can access and assimilate advanced technologies and knowhow by <strong>in</strong>teract<strong>in</strong>g with local<br />

technological and <strong>in</strong>novative leaders such as scientists and eng<strong>in</strong>eers <strong>in</strong> local companies, research labs,<br />

and universities (Almeida and Kogut, 1999; Mansfield and Romeo, 1980). Lastly, by locat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a DM,<br />

the subsidiaries of EM MNEs ga<strong>in</strong> opportunities to hire high-quality graduates <strong>in</strong> local universities and<br />

R&D workers from local labor markets (Møen, 2005).<br />

Knowledge Transfer from Subsidiaries <strong>in</strong> <strong>Developed</strong> <strong>Market</strong>s to Parents <strong>in</strong> <strong>Emerg<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Market</strong>s<br />

In addition to obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g knowledge from the advanced host markets, subsidiaries of EM MNEs<br />

also have to organize transference of such knowledge back to their parent companies <strong>in</strong> their home<br />

markets through several <strong>in</strong>ternal mechanisms. The subsidiaries <strong>in</strong> DMs provide learn<strong>in</strong>g opportunities<br />

for parent companies by serv<strong>in</strong>g as a platform for parent companies to access technologies, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g<br />

those embedded <strong>in</strong> products and human resources. For example, parents <strong>in</strong> EMs can send home-market<br />

researchers to the DM affiliates to observe, absorb technological knowledge, and augment skills on a<br />

regular basis (Liu and Buck, 2007). Parent companies <strong>in</strong> EMs can import advanced products made by<br />

its DM affiliates and obta<strong>in</strong> relevant knowhow <strong>in</strong> produc<strong>in</strong>g, us<strong>in</strong>g, and improv<strong>in</strong>g the products<br />

(Javorcik, 2004). Parents <strong>in</strong> EMs can also have R&D researchers <strong>in</strong> DM subsidiaries tra<strong>in</strong><br />

home-market employees, or directly move some of the foreign-subsidiary researchers <strong>in</strong>to the parent<br />

companies (Cheung and L<strong>in</strong>, 2004; Görg, Strobl and Walsh, 2005).<br />

A parent-subsidiary relationship enables transfer of not only codified resources (licenses and<br />

patents <strong>in</strong> the market) but also more important, tacit resources such as R&D knowhow and skills,<br />

which are difficult for the parent companies to obta<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> the market (Kogut and Zander, 1993; Keller,<br />

2002; 2004). Transfer of tacit knowledge is more effective with<strong>in</strong> the company than <strong>in</strong> the market<br />

because the company allows direct, frequent <strong>in</strong>teractions between the “teachers” (the subsidiaries) and<br />

the “students” (the parents) and development of shared language of communication, standardization<br />

and codification, which are critical to tacit knowledge transfer (Grant, 1996; Kogut and Zander, 1993;<br />

Lyles and Salk, 1996).<br />

Although <strong>in</strong>ternal knowledge transfer mechanisms are necessary for EM MNE parents to<br />

benefit from knowledge spillovers, they are not sufficient. Indeed, knowledge spillovers <strong>in</strong> the host<br />

6


markets and <strong>in</strong>ternal transfer mechanisms are jo<strong>in</strong>tly required <strong>in</strong> order that a positive reverse spillover<br />

effect is observed, and are <strong>in</strong> practice difficult to disentangle from one another (e.g., Belderbos,<br />

Lykogianni, and Veugelers, 2008; Sanna-Randaccio and Veugelers, 2007). Sanna-Randaccio and<br />

Veugelers (2007), for <strong>in</strong>stance, argued that an MNE has to organize the <strong>in</strong>ternal transfer of know-how<br />

that is be<strong>in</strong>g sourced externally if it is to benefit from the knowledge. The previous literature focus<strong>in</strong>g<br />

on knowledge-seek<strong>in</strong>g OFDI of EM MNEs (e.g., Bertoni et al., 2008; Buckley et al., 2007) also<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicates that EM MNEs choose locations <strong>in</strong> order to access knowledge and implies that they on<br />

average are likely to take proactive steps to ensure that knowledge is transferred.<br />

In summary, OFDI <strong>in</strong> developed markets improves technological capabilities of EM MNE<br />

parent firms through knowledge spillovers from companies <strong>in</strong> developed markets to subsidiaries of<br />

EM MNEs <strong>in</strong> those markets as well as through knowledge transfer from the subsidiaries back to parent<br />

firms <strong>in</strong> emerg<strong>in</strong>g markets. We therefore reach the follow<strong>in</strong>g hypothesis.<br />

Hypothesis 1: All other th<strong>in</strong>gs be<strong>in</strong>g equal, the richer the technological resources <strong>in</strong> a host<br />

developed market where an EM MNE <strong>in</strong>vests, the greater is the impact on the technological<br />

capabilities of the EM MNE parent.<br />

Data and Sample<br />

METHODS<br />

The major data source for EM MNE parent <strong>in</strong>formation is Bureau van Dijk (BvD) Orbis, which<br />

records parent-affiliate relations and f<strong>in</strong>ancial statements for over 60 million companies across the<br />

world. The data sources for <strong>in</strong>dustry- and country-level <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong>clude SourceOECD, World<br />

Bank World Development Indicators (WDI), and Klynveld Peat Marwick Goerdeler (KPMG). Data<br />

for distance measures between countries were collected from Centre d'Etudes Prospectives et<br />

d'Informations Internationales (CEPII).<br />

Based on the BvD Orbis database, we first selected parent companies from emerg<strong>in</strong>g markets.<br />

These companies were registered <strong>in</strong> an EM and not owned by other entities (i.e., they were the global<br />

ultimate owner). We adopted EM classifications us<strong>in</strong>g three sources, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the literature survey by<br />

Hoskisson, Eden, Lau, and Wright (2000) on emerg<strong>in</strong>g economies, and two major f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>dex<strong>in</strong>g<br />

sources, Morgan Stanley Capital International (MSCI) Barra 2010 and F<strong>in</strong>ancial Times Stock<br />

7


Exchange (FTSE) Group 2010. We excluded economies that had jo<strong>in</strong>ed the Organization for<br />

Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) by 2010. The f<strong>in</strong>al EM list <strong>in</strong> our study <strong>in</strong>cludes 57<br />

economies 1<br />

We further removed those firms that had persistently reported zero R&D expenditure between<br />

2000 and 2008 (the sample years) because technological capabilities are probably not critical for the<br />

performance of these companies (and also because they do not provide variation for the <strong>in</strong>dependent<br />

variable). As a result, the sample consists of 9,953 EM parents (hereafter referred to as the larger EM<br />

sample). As we will expla<strong>in</strong> later, the larger EM sample was used to calculate a control variable. Last,<br />

we kept only those that have foreign subsidiaries <strong>in</strong> DMs, where DMs refer to high-<strong>in</strong>come OECD<br />

countries as of 2010<br />

.<br />

2<br />

.<br />

The f<strong>in</strong>al sample is a panel dataset with 493 EM MNE parents from 2000 to 2008. These<br />

companies are from 20 different EMs, 43 different <strong>in</strong>dustries (based on 2-digit US SIC codes) and 27<br />

different host DMs. Specifically, 75% of the companies are from India, Turkey, and Israel, 44% are <strong>in</strong><br />

electronic and other electric equipment, <strong>in</strong>dustrial mach<strong>in</strong>ery and equipment, and chemicals and allied<br />

products, 62% <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> Germany, Netherlands, United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, and the United States.<br />

Variables and Measurements<br />

Dependent Variable<br />

We used firm-level R&D expenditures as a proxy for EM MNEs’ technological capability,<br />

follow<strong>in</strong>g Bays<strong>in</strong>ger and Hoskisson (1989), Markides and Ittner (1994), and Hundley, Jacobson, and<br />

Park (1996) 3<br />

. Such <strong>in</strong>formation is available <strong>in</strong> company f<strong>in</strong>ancial statements from BvD Orbis.<br />

1<br />

Albania, Argent<strong>in</strong>a, Armenia, Azerbaijan, Bangladesh, Belarus, Bosnia and Herzegov<strong>in</strong>a, Botswana, Brazil, Bulgaria,<br />

Chile, Ch<strong>in</strong>a, Colombia, Cote d'Ivoire, Croatia, Czech Republic, Ecuador, Egypt, Estonia, Georgia, Ghana, Hungary, India,<br />

Indonesia, Israel, Jamaica, Jordan, Kazakhstan, Kenya, Kyrgyzstan, Latvia, Lithuania, Macedonia, Malaysia, Mauritius,<br />

Mexico, Moldova, Morocco, Nigeria, Pakistan, Peru, Philipp<strong>in</strong>es, Poland, Romania, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Slovenia, South<br />

Africa, South Korea, Sri Lanka, Taiwan, Tajikistan, Thailand, Tr<strong>in</strong>idad and Tobago, Tunisia, Turkey, Turkmenistan,<br />

Ukra<strong>in</strong>e, Uzbekistan, Venezuela, and Zimbabwe.<br />

2<br />

Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, F<strong>in</strong>land, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan,<br />

Luxembourg, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Slovak Republic, Spa<strong>in</strong>, Sweden, Switzerland, United<br />

K<strong>in</strong>gdom, and United States.<br />

3<br />

We were unable to measure <strong>in</strong>novation output measures of parent firms due to data limitations. A robustness check us<strong>in</strong>g<br />

R&D output measures such as values of new products would be a valuable extension of this study.<br />

8


Independent Variables<br />

To capture level of technological resources <strong>in</strong> a host DM, we used three country-<strong>in</strong>dustry level<br />

measures. Country-<strong>in</strong>dustry level measures are preferred over country level measures because<br />

technological knowledge is ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong>dustry specific (Griliches, 1984, 1992; Pater and Pavitt, 1997).<br />

We utilized 3-digit SIC codes to classify <strong>in</strong>dustries for these measures. Information for all three<br />

measures is available <strong>in</strong> SourceOECD.<br />

Measure 1, host DM’s number of R&D employment, is calculated as <strong>in</strong>dustry-level number of<br />

R&D workers <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g researchers and technicians <strong>in</strong> a host DM. This measure captures the<br />

host-market endowment <strong>in</strong> R&D expertise, skills, and specialized knowledge embodied <strong>in</strong> human<br />

resources (Song, Almeida, and Wu, 2003).<br />

Measure 2, host DM’s dollar value of R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments, is measured as <strong>in</strong>dustry-level dollar<br />

values of R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> a host DM. This measure captures spend<strong>in</strong>g on R&D activities<br />

<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g, for example, salaries for R&D workers and <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> build<strong>in</strong>g technological networks<br />

with local research <strong>in</strong>stitutions and other companies. This measure reflects firms’ total efforts <strong>in</strong> R&D<br />

activities, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g those that fail to yield any registered patents and <strong>in</strong>ventions (Gornik-Tomaszewski<br />

and Millan, 2005).<br />

Measure 3, host DM’s number of patents applied, is calculated as <strong>in</strong>dustry-level number of<br />

patents applied by both residents and non-residents <strong>in</strong> a DM. This measure <strong>in</strong> general suggests the<br />

regional assets of codified, published R&D knowledge (Comanor and Scherer, 1969; Keller, 2004).<br />

In the cases where an EM parent company holds affiliates <strong>in</strong> multiple DMs, we used arithmetic<br />

means and summations to capture host countries’ technological resources for the EM parent. For<br />

robustness checks, we used two composite measures: means of technological resources <strong>in</strong> host<br />

countries weighted by each host DM’s market size, or weighted by the geographic distance to the home<br />

market.<br />

Control Variables<br />

We first <strong>in</strong>cluded four firm-level control variables. First, s<strong>in</strong>ce larger firms will be more<br />

capable of <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> R&D activities (Shefer and Frenkel, 2005), we controlled for firm size,<br />

measured as the logarithm of the dollar value of total assets. Second, prior studies suggested that young<br />

firms enjoy less <strong>in</strong>ertia and commit more to <strong>in</strong>novation (Balasubramanian and Lee, 2008; Hansen,<br />

9


1992), and therefore we controlled for firm age, measured as the logarithm of the number of years<br />

s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>in</strong>corporation. In addition, follow<strong>in</strong>g the studies that a firm’s R&D expenditure is sensitive to its<br />

f<strong>in</strong>ancial stress (Hall and Mansfield, 1971; Ozkan, 2002), we <strong>in</strong>cluded two firm-level variables<br />

reflect<strong>in</strong>g a firm’s f<strong>in</strong>ancial situation: firm current ratio, calculated as the ratio of current assets to<br />

current liabilities, measur<strong>in</strong>g short-term liquidity stress, and firm solvency ratio, calculated as the ratio<br />

of total assets to total liabilities, measur<strong>in</strong>g long-term solvency stress. All the firm-level <strong>in</strong>formation is<br />

available <strong>in</strong> company f<strong>in</strong>ancial statements from BvD Orbis.<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ce an EM MNE’s R&D expenditure is also affected by technological resources <strong>in</strong> its home<br />

market (Branstetter, 2001; Thompson and Fox-Kean, 2005), we also <strong>in</strong>cluded home R&D environment,<br />

calculated as the logarithm of <strong>in</strong>dustry-level R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> a specific EM <strong>in</strong> a year normalized<br />

by the arithmetic mean of <strong>in</strong>dustry-level R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> all EM s <strong>in</strong> that year. 4<br />

We used the larger<br />

EM sample to calculate this measure.<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ce the economic relations between countries may <strong>in</strong>fluence the rate of <strong>in</strong>ternational<br />

technology diffusion (Spencer, 1965), we controlled for three variables that determ<strong>in</strong>e bilateral<br />

economic relations follow<strong>in</strong>g the Gravity model <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational economics (Bergstrand, 1985). The<br />

variables are home market size and host market size, both measured as logarithms of real GDP<br />

compiled by the World Bank’s WDI database, and weighted geographic distance between home and<br />

host markets, which is measured as the logarithm of the composite of geographic distances between<br />

two markets’ major metropolitan cities weighted by each city’s population. The distance <strong>in</strong>formation is<br />

available at CEPII. By <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g host market size, we also controlled for market-seek<strong>in</strong>g motives for<br />

EM MNEs <strong>in</strong>to DMs (Buckley et al., 2007).<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, we <strong>in</strong>cluded a dummy variable common official language, which is 1 if both countries<br />

share the same official language and is 0 otherwise, to control for l<strong>in</strong>guistic and cultural barriers that<br />

may h<strong>in</strong>der knowledge spillovers <strong>in</strong> a host country (Guellec and de la Potterie, 2001). We also <strong>in</strong>cluded<br />

home tax burden, measured as effective corporate tax rate <strong>in</strong> home countries, to measure parent<br />

companies’ taxation burdens, an <strong>in</strong>stitutional factor that can affect available fund<strong>in</strong>g for R&D<br />

activities (Hall, 1993). This <strong>in</strong>formation was collected from KPMG Global Tax Survey. To control for<br />

period- and country-specific effects, we <strong>in</strong>cluded a series of dummies for year, home countries, and<br />

4<br />

Some observations report zero R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments as the base for the logarithm, so we add a positive amount to all<br />

observations to ensure all observations to be positive before tak<strong>in</strong>g the logarithm.<br />

10


host countries.<br />

Estimation Model<br />

We used panel Tobit estimation model for the empirical analyses:<br />

*<br />

ln(R & D expenditurei,<br />

t ) = α + βln(DM's<br />

richness <strong>in</strong> R & D resources<br />

+ γ ln(the mth flow or stock based control variable )<br />

+<br />

∑<br />

∑<br />

m m<br />

δ<br />

k k<br />

(the<br />

kth<br />

other<br />

control<br />

variable<br />

i, t<br />

) + ε<br />

where i stands for EM parent firm i, t for years, and r for the number of year lags. We expla<strong>in</strong> our<br />

model <strong>in</strong> depth below.<br />

i, t<br />

First, we adopted Tobit panel <strong>in</strong>stead of l<strong>in</strong>ear panel estimation models because the dependent<br />

variable, EM MNEs’ technological capabilities, presents a corner solution issue. Specifically, an EM<br />

parent firm chooses host country-<strong>in</strong>dustry to improve its proprietary R&D activities measured by R&D<br />

expenditures subject to the constra<strong>in</strong>t that R&D expenditures cannot be less than zero (<strong>in</strong> our sample<br />

12% of the observations reported zero R&D expenditures 5 ). Tobit models can be used to address the<br />

corner solution issue (McDonald and Moffitt, 1980). Specifically, the dependent variable is expressed<br />

as a non-negative latent variable 6 (e.g., Tob<strong>in</strong>, 1958),<br />

ln(R & D<br />

expenditure<br />

i, t<br />

)<br />

*<br />

⎧<br />

= ⎨<br />

⎩ln(R<br />

& D<br />

0<br />

expenditure<br />

i, t<br />

i, t<br />

, if<br />

+ 1) , if<br />

R & D<br />

R & D<br />

i, t−r<br />

)<br />

expenditure<br />

expenditure<br />

In the panel regressions, we adopted random effects rather than fixed effects models because<br />

fixed effects models are technically unavailable <strong>in</strong> non-l<strong>in</strong>ear models such as Tobit (Greene, 2004).<br />

Second, <strong>in</strong>stead of us<strong>in</strong>g orig<strong>in</strong>al values, we used changes (or growth) of values for most<br />

variables (the exceptions are current and solvency ratios, tax burden, and dummies), follow<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

Cobb-Douglass logarithm-logarithm transformation of production resources (e.g., Either, 1982; Keller,<br />

2002, 2004). The logarithmic transformation presents several advantages. First, tak<strong>in</strong>g the logarithm<br />

transformation of a flow or stock value suggests change or growth of the value, and can thus reduce<br />

co-<strong>in</strong>tegration concerns (i.e., EM parent’s R&D expenditures and host-market technological resources<br />

are both expand<strong>in</strong>g simply because of a general global grow<strong>in</strong>g trend <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>novation) (e.g., Godfrey,<br />

5<br />

Although, as discussed, we removed all observations that consistently reported zero <strong>in</strong> all years between 2000 and 2008,<br />

we kept those that reported zero <strong>in</strong> only some of the years but were positive <strong>in</strong> other years.<br />

6<br />

We added one to each orig<strong>in</strong>al value before tak<strong>in</strong>g the logarithm, which requires that the base be positive.<br />

,<br />

i, t<br />

i, t<br />

= 0<br />

> 0<br />

11


McAleer, and McKenzie, 1988). Second, the Gravity model of <strong>in</strong>ternational economics suggests that a<br />

logarithm-logarithm function of both home and host markets’ sizes and their distance can capture<br />

potential economic relations between the two markets, which is an important control variable as shown<br />

above (Bergstrand, 1985). Third, results of a logarithm-logarithm econometric model show directly<br />

the scale-free marg<strong>in</strong>al effects of an <strong>in</strong>dependent variable on the dependent variable (Greene, 2004).<br />

Last, s<strong>in</strong>ce knowledge transfer takes time, we used 4-year lagged values of the measurements<br />

for technological resources <strong>in</strong> host countries <strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> regression models. We followed Mansfield<br />

(1985) and Mansfield and Romeo (1980), who found that knowledge spillovers of MNEs to local firms<br />

<strong>in</strong> a host market took on average four years. Other scholars have argued that time needed for<br />

technology diffusion varies depend<strong>in</strong>g on many factors (e.g., <strong>in</strong>formation barriers) and can even be<br />

“stochastic” (Keller, 2004: 755). Therefore, for robustness checks, we also used alternative lag values<br />

for technological resources <strong>in</strong> host markets (between 0 and 5). Us<strong>in</strong>g lagged values of host country<br />

technological endowments can also ensure the direction of causality (Jung and Marshall, 1985); it is<br />

more likely that past regional technological resources <strong>in</strong> a host market affect an EM MNE’s future<br />

firm-level technological capabilities rather than the reverse.<br />

Hausman Tests for Endogeneity<br />

A potential concern of the empirical analyses is that host countries’ technological resources are<br />

endogenous – that is, host country resources may be correlated with the error term <strong>in</strong> the regression<br />

models. The endogeneity may be due to omitted variables or simultaneity (e.g., host country<br />

technological resources are a function of parent firms’ technological capabilities). In this case, the<br />

Tobit estimator is biased and <strong>in</strong>consistent (Greene, 2004). We therefore adopted Hausman tests to<br />

assess the extent to which endogeneity of host country resources is a serious problem and the necessity<br />

to resort to alternative methods (Baum, 2006; Hausman, 1978; Wooldridge, 2002). To implement the<br />

Hausman tests, we chose an <strong>in</strong>strumental variable (IV) – the effective corporate tax rate of the host<br />

market, which has no direct effects on the R&D activities of a parent firm that is registered <strong>in</strong> different<br />

taxation legislation but determ<strong>in</strong>es the systematic f<strong>in</strong>ancial stress on host-market economic activities<br />

such as <strong>in</strong>novation. In Step One, we regressed each of the three measures for the <strong>in</strong>dependent variable<br />

on the IV. In Step Two, we <strong>in</strong>cluded the residual term from Step One <strong>in</strong>to the ma<strong>in</strong> econometric<br />

specification, and tested the null hypothesis that the parameter estimate for the residual is zero – if the<br />

12


estimate is significantly different from zero, there is endogeneity.<br />

Table 1A reports the first step results which suggest that the effective corporate tax rate of the<br />

host market is a good IV because it is significantly correlated with all three measures for host country<br />

technological resources. Table 1B reports the second step results with the T-test for the significance of<br />

the residual’s parameter estimate. Table 1B shows that the estimates for the residuals collected <strong>in</strong> Step<br />

One are not significantly different from zero, which suggests that endogeneity is not a problem, and<br />

allows us to use the orig<strong>in</strong>al econometric specification. We also replicated the tests by us<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

summation measures for the host market’s technological resources and by us<strong>in</strong>g different year lags,<br />

and found similar results.<br />

[Insert Table 1A here]<br />

[Insert Table 1B here]<br />

RESULTS<br />

Table 2 presents summary statistics and the correlation matrix for all the variables, which<br />

suggest that multicoll<strong>in</strong>earity is not a concern for the study.<br />

[Insert Table 2 here]<br />

Table 3 reports regression results us<strong>in</strong>g three different measures for the <strong>in</strong>dependent variable.<br />

The results <strong>in</strong> Table 3 show supportive evidence for our hypothesis when technological resources <strong>in</strong><br />

the host market are measured by R&D. Both R&D measures 1 (host-market number of R&D<br />

employment) and 2 (host-market dollar value of R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments) have significant, positive effects<br />

on the R&D expenditures of EM MNEs’ parent companies <strong>in</strong> the home markets. For <strong>in</strong>stance, Model 1<br />

shows that when the number of <strong>in</strong>dustry-level R&D employment <strong>in</strong> a DM host market <strong>in</strong>creased by 1%<br />

four years ago, the current R&D expenditures of the EM parent <strong>in</strong>crease by 0.20%; Model 3 shows that<br />

when the dollar value of <strong>in</strong>dustry-level R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> a DM host market <strong>in</strong>creased by 1% four<br />

years ago, the current R&D expenditures of the EM parent <strong>in</strong>crease by 0.10%. In addition, the overall<br />

explanatory power of the econometric specification is strong; Chi square values (goodness of fit tests)<br />

for all models are high and P-values (probability to reject the significance of all variables) are<br />

consistently close to zeros for all models.<br />

[Insert Table 3 here]<br />

13


However, results us<strong>in</strong>g measure 3 (host-market number of patents applied) suggest that an EM<br />

parent with affiliates <strong>in</strong> a patent-rich DM is not significantly more active <strong>in</strong> R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments. We<br />

speculate that as patents represent codified, quantified knowledge and are tradable <strong>in</strong> the market, EM<br />

MNEs can access such knowledge through market transactions (e.g., direct acquisitions of patents,<br />

licens<strong>in</strong>g) (David, 1992; Grabowski, 1968; Griliches, 1984). Therefore, even if EM MNEs have no<br />

direct presence <strong>in</strong> a patent-rich host market, they can still tap <strong>in</strong>to patent resources <strong>in</strong> that market.<br />

Other R&D resources such as R&D skills and know-how embedded <strong>in</strong> technological networks and<br />

R&D personnel, however, are more tacit, non-codified, and are ma<strong>in</strong>ly accessible when EM MNEs<br />

locate subsidiaries <strong>in</strong> the market (Polanyi, 1958; Keller, 2004).<br />

Some results for the control variables are worth not<strong>in</strong>g. First, the positive and significant<br />

effects of home R&D environment suggest that an R&D-active environment at home encourages the<br />

parent companies to be more technologically active. Second, both home and host market sizes have<br />

positive effects on parent companies’ R&D, which suggests that the fixed cost nature of R&D<br />

expenditures requires access to large markets. We also found that the geographic distance between<br />

markets has a negative effect, confirm<strong>in</strong>g the idea that any <strong>in</strong>ternational knowledge diffusion is likely<br />

to decay over distance (Conley and Ligon, 2002; Maurseth and Verspagen, 2002; Sjöholm, 1996;<br />

Keller, 2004). Lastly, the results that firm size has a positive effect and firm age has a negative effect on<br />

parent companies’ R&D expenditure confirm prior f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs that large firms are more capable of<br />

<strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> R&D activities but old firms are less motivated to be <strong>in</strong>novative (e.g., Balasubramanian<br />

and Lee, 2008; Hansen, 1992; Shefer and Frenkel, 2005).<br />

Robustness Checks<br />

First, we relaxed the assumption based on Mansfield (1985) and Mansfield and Romeo (1980)<br />

that a four-year time lag is needed for technology diffusion. Instead, we used a wider range of possible<br />

numbers of year lags (between 0 and 5). Table 4 shows the results us<strong>in</strong>g our first measure of<br />

technological resources <strong>in</strong> the host market. Specifically, we found that host country number of R&D<br />

employment <strong>in</strong> the current year or one to five years ago generates significant, positive spillover<br />

benefits that improve EM MNEs’ technological capabilities. These results are highly consistent with<br />

our ma<strong>in</strong> regression results <strong>in</strong> Table 3. We further replicated these robustness tests us<strong>in</strong>g measures 2<br />

14


and 3, and obta<strong>in</strong>ed similar results as those <strong>in</strong> Table 3, that is, host market R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments have<br />

significant, positive effects on EM MNEs’ technological capabilities, whereas host market patents<br />

have <strong>in</strong>significant effects.<br />

[Insert Table 4 here]<br />

Second, we adopted alternative composite measures for host market technological resources.<br />

We first used the mean values of the measures for technological resources weighted by host market<br />

real gross domestic product (GDP). We chose host country market size GDP as the weight because<br />

accord<strong>in</strong>g to the market-seek<strong>in</strong>g view (e.g., Buckley et al., 2007), an EM MNE tends to focus more on<br />

larger economies which present potentially more economic opportunities. The second alternative<br />

measure is the mean value of the measures for technological resources weighted by the home-host<br />

market geographic distance. S<strong>in</strong>ce it is relatively easy for an EM parent’s employees to travel to a<br />

closer foreign market for R&D related collaborations and <strong>in</strong>teractions (e.g., Sjöholm, 1996), there<br />

might be more opportunities for an EM parent to access R&D resources <strong>in</strong> a more proximate location.<br />

Table 5 shows the results for these alternative <strong>in</strong>dependent variables, which are aga<strong>in</strong> very similar to<br />

the previous regression results; that is, R&D-related measures have consistently positive and<br />

significant impacts, whereas the number of patents does not show any significant effect.<br />

[Insert Table 5 here]<br />

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION<br />

This study focuses on the implications of conduct<strong>in</strong>g OFDI <strong>in</strong> developed markets on the<br />

technological capabilities of emerg<strong>in</strong>g market MNEs. Although it has been well recognized that OFDI<br />

<strong>in</strong> developed markets is largely driven by knowledge seek<strong>in</strong>g by EM MNEs (Braconier, Ekholm, and<br />

Knarvik, 2001; Mak<strong>in</strong>o, Lau, and Yeh, 2002; Mathews and Zander, 2007; Luo and Tung, 2007; Rui<br />

and Yip, 2008; Deng, 2009), little is known about whether and to what extent such OFDI does <strong>in</strong> fact<br />

generates positive knowledge spillover effects that augment the technological capabilities of the EM<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestors. Our study contributes to this research topic. Us<strong>in</strong>g a panel dataset of 493 EM MNEs from 20<br />

EMs over the period 2000-2008, and controll<strong>in</strong>g for possible endogeneity, we found robust evidence<br />

15


that <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> host markets that are rich <strong>in</strong> technological resources contributes to the technological<br />

development of EM MNEs. Specifically, we found that technological resources measured by R&D<br />

employment and R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> a host market-<strong>in</strong>dustry do generate significant, positive<br />

spillovers that improve R&D activeness of EM MNE parent companies. However, when technological<br />

resources are measured by the number of patents <strong>in</strong> a host market-<strong>in</strong>dustry, no such significant positive<br />

spillover effects are observed.<br />

These results suggest that the OFDI-related spillover benefits of technology depend on the<br />

nature of the knowledge. A possible explanation for our results is that because patents are codified,<br />

quantifiable knowledge, which is also published and tradable <strong>in</strong> the market (Grabowski, 1968;<br />

Griliches, 1984), EM MNEs, even without a presence <strong>in</strong> a host market, can acquire or license patents<br />

through market transactions (David, 1992; Keller, 2004). Moreover, by their nature, patents are<br />

designed to protect <strong>in</strong>ventors, allow access only through licens<strong>in</strong>g payment or other forms of rights<br />

acquisition, and thus prevent unwanted (albeit imperfectly) knowledge spillovers by, for <strong>in</strong>stance,<br />

unpaid imitation and duplication of patent codes (e.g., Cohen, Goto, Nagata, Nelson, and Walsh, 2001;<br />

Owen-Smith and Powell, 2004; Schmidt, 2006). Thus, it is perhaps not surpris<strong>in</strong>g that we found no<br />

evidence that be<strong>in</strong>g present <strong>in</strong> host markets that have high levels of patent activity leads to significant<br />

knowledge spillover benefits for EM MNEs.<br />

The literature suggests that relative to codified knowledge, tacit, less codified R&D knowledge<br />

is probably more critical for firm <strong>in</strong>novation (e.g., Qu<strong>in</strong>tas, Lefrere, and Jones, 1997). Such tacit<br />

knowledge is embedded <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>novative process, technological networks and human resources (e.g.,<br />

Breschi and Lissoni, 2001; Fritsch, 2004). Our results are consistent with this literature, and suggest<br />

that OFDI-related reverse spillovers occur because <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g firms are able to access location-bound<br />

R&D resources and networks of researchers. Relative to the number of patents, measures of R&D<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments and number of R&D employment reflect tacit resources such as technological networks,<br />

<strong>in</strong>novative activities and effort, and specialized knowledge embodied <strong>in</strong> humans<br />

(Gornik-Tomaszewski and Millan, 2005; Song, Almeida, and Wu, 2003). For example, personal<br />

experiences <strong>in</strong> research experiments are tacit, non-patented, and embodied <strong>in</strong> relevant researchers,<br />

who can be hired to demonstrate and teach those experiences to another employer (Breschi and Lissoni,<br />

2001); an <strong>in</strong>novative activity, whose cost is recorded as an R&D <strong>in</strong>vestment, may be designed to<br />

produce un-codified, non-patented knowledge, rather than a registered patent (Horstmann, MacDonald,<br />

16


and Sliv<strong>in</strong>ski, 1985.<br />

These f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs have two key implications for practices related to knowledge seek<strong>in</strong>g through<br />

OFDI. First, EM MNEs <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> knowledge acquisition should actively conduct FDI <strong>in</strong> markets<br />

that are rich <strong>in</strong> technological resources. Several real life examples (e.g., Geely’s acquisition of Volvo)<br />

suggest that EM MNEs pay attention to technological resources embedded <strong>in</strong> firms <strong>in</strong> developed<br />

markets (People’s Daily, 2010). Our study suggests that they should also attach importance to the<br />

richness of technological resources <strong>in</strong> a host market <strong>in</strong> general. Such market-<strong>in</strong>dustry level of<br />

knowledge resources <strong>in</strong> a host market can also generate significant spillovers on EM MNEs at home.<br />

The second implication of our study is that for EM MNEs that seek knowledge to augment their<br />

technological capabilities, they should probably pay more attention to tacit measures for technological<br />

capabilities (e.g., R&D <strong>in</strong>vestment and number of R&D employment) rather than codified measures<br />

(e.g., patents) <strong>in</strong> host market <strong>in</strong>dustries.<br />

Future studies can extend our research <strong>in</strong> multiple ways. First, future studies can <strong>in</strong>vestigate<br />

factors that moderate the knowledge spillover effects of OFDI <strong>in</strong> developed markets. The exist<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>novation literature suggests the importance of company-level factors such as absorptive capacity<br />

(Cohen and Lev<strong>in</strong>thal, 1990; Griffith, Redd<strong>in</strong>g, and Reenen, 2003), <strong>in</strong>dustry-level factors such as<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry competition (Sakakibara, 2002), and country-level factors such as capacity of host-market<br />

<strong>in</strong>novation networks (Muller and Zenker, 2001; Zhao, 2006). Second, one can conduct robustness<br />

checks of our empirical f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs by, for <strong>in</strong>stance, measur<strong>in</strong>g the firm-level technological capabilities<br />

measure with parent companies’ number of patents, number of citations of their patents, and<br />

<strong>in</strong>novative output measures such as new product development and commercialization values of patents<br />

as suggested by Comanor and Scherer (1969) and Acs, Ansel<strong>in</strong>, and Varga (2001). F<strong>in</strong>ally, s<strong>in</strong>ce the<br />

knowledge levels of subsidiaries as well as effectiveness of knowledge transfer to parent companies<br />

are also determ<strong>in</strong>ed by the operational modes of subsidiaries (e.g., majority- or m<strong>in</strong>ority ownership)<br />

(e.g., Blomström and Sjöholm, 1999), and the mode of entry (e.g., Greenfield or mergers and<br />

acquisitions) (e.g., Belderbos, 2003; Grünfeld and Sanna-Randaccio, 2005), the third potential<br />

extension is to address whether and how the degree of spillovers differs across different operational<br />

and entry modes. These potential studies would however require development of new databases.<br />

17


ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS<br />

We thank the editors Peter Gammeltoft, Igor Filatotchev, Bersant Hobdari, and all<br />

participants at the 2 nd<br />

Copenhagen Conference on “<strong>Emerg<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Mult<strong>in</strong>ational</strong>s”, and Steven<br />

Globerman and David Thomas for their helpful comments. This research was supported <strong>in</strong><br />

part by the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada (No. 752-2009-1880<br />

05) and the Jack Aust<strong>in</strong> Centre for Asia-Pacific Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Studies at the Segal Graduate School<br />

of Bus<strong>in</strong>ess, Simon Fraser University.<br />

REFERENCES<br />

Acs, Z.J., Ansel<strong>in</strong>, L., and Varga, A. (2002). Patents and Innovation Counts as Measures of Regional<br />

Production of New Knowledge. Research Policy, 31, 1069-1085.<br />

Almeida, P., and Kogut, B. (1999). Localization of knowledge and the mobility of eng<strong>in</strong>eers <strong>in</strong><br />

regional networks. Management Science, 45(7), 905-917.<br />

Aitken, B.J. and Harrison, A.E. (1999). Do Domestic Firms Benefit from Direct Foreign Investment?<br />

Evidence from Venezuela. The American Economic Review, 89(3), 605-618.<br />

Atk<strong>in</strong>son, A. B., and Stiglitz, J. E. (1969). A new view of technological change. The Economic Journal,<br />

79(315), 573-578.<br />

Aubert, J-E. (2004). Promot<strong>in</strong>g Innovation <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries: A Conceptual Framework.<br />

World Bank Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper No. 3554.<br />

Balasubramanian, N., and Lee, J. (2008). Firm Age and Innovation. Industrial and Corporate Change,<br />

17(5), 1019-1047.<br />

Baum, C. F. 2006. An Introduction to Modern Econometrics Us<strong>in</strong>g Stata. College Station, TX: Stata<br />

Press.<br />

Belderbos, R. (2003). Entry Mode, Organizational Learn<strong>in</strong>g, and R&D <strong>in</strong> Foreign Affiliates: Evidence<br />

from Japanese Firm. Strategic Management Journal, 24(3), 235-259.<br />

Belderbos, R., Lykogianni, E., and Veugelers, R. (2008). Strategic R&D Location by <strong>Mult<strong>in</strong>ational</strong><br />

Firms: Spillovers, Technology Sourc<strong>in</strong>g, and Competition. Journal of Economics and<br />

Management Strategy, 17(3), 759-779.<br />

Bergstrand, J. H. (1989). The Generalized Gravity Equation, Monopolistic Competition, and the<br />

Factor-Proportions Theory <strong>in</strong> International Trade. The Review of Economics and Statistics,<br />

71(1), 143-153.<br />

Bertoni, F., Elia, S., and Rabbiosi, L. (2008). Driver of acquisitions from BRICs to advanced countries:<br />

Firm-level evidence, DIG - Politecnico di Milano Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper.<br />

Blomström, M. and Sjöholm, F.(1999). Technology Transfer and Spillovers: Does Local Participation<br />

with <strong>Mult<strong>in</strong>ational</strong>s Matter? European Economic Review, 43(4-6), 915-923.<br />

Branstetter, L.G. (2001). Are Knowledge Spillovers International or Intranational <strong>in</strong> Scope?<br />

Microeconometric evidence from the U.S. and Japan. Journal of International Economics,<br />

53(1), 53-79.<br />

18


Breschi, S. and Lissoni, F. (2001). Knowledge spillovers and local <strong>in</strong>novation systems: A critical<br />

survey. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10(4), 975-1005.<br />

Brouwer, E. and Kle<strong>in</strong>knecht, A. (1999). Keynes-plus? Effective demand and change <strong>in</strong> firm-level<br />

R&D: An empirical note. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 23(3), 385-399.<br />

Buckley, P. J., Clegg, L. J., Cross, A. R., Liu, X., Voss, H., and Zheng, P. (2007). The determ<strong>in</strong>ants of<br />

Ch<strong>in</strong>ese outward foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestment. Journal of International Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Studies, 38(4),<br />

499-518.<br />

Buckley, P.J., Elia, S., and Kafouros, M. (2010). Acquisitions from emerg<strong>in</strong>g countries: What factors<br />

<strong>in</strong>fluence the performance of target firms <strong>in</strong> advanced countries? European Journal of<br />

International Management, 4(1/2), 30-47.<br />

Cantwell, J. (1989). Technological Innovation and <strong>Mult<strong>in</strong>ational</strong> Corporations. Blackwell: Oxford<br />

and Cambridge.<br />

Caves, R.E. (1996). Economic Analysis of the <strong>Mult<strong>in</strong>ational</strong> Enterprise. Cambridge University Press:<br />

Cambridge, UK.<br />

Cham<strong>in</strong>ade, C. and Vang, J. (2006). Globalisation of Knowledge Production and Regional Innovation<br />

Policy: Support<strong>in</strong>g Specialized Hubs <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries. CIRCLE of Lund University<br />

Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper No. 2006/15.<br />

Cheung, K.-y., and L<strong>in</strong>, P. (2004). Spillover effects of FDI on <strong>in</strong>novation <strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>a: Evidence from the<br />

prov<strong>in</strong>cial data. Ch<strong>in</strong>a Economic Review, 15(1), 25-44.<br />

Child, J., and Rodrigues, S. B. (2005). The <strong>in</strong>ternationalization of Ch<strong>in</strong>ese firms: A case for theoretical<br />

extension? . Management and Organization Review, 1(3), 381-410.<br />

Cohen, W.M., Goto, A., Nagata, A., Nelson, R., and Walsh, J. (2001). R&D spillovers, patents and the<br />

<strong>in</strong>centives to <strong>in</strong>novate <strong>in</strong> Japan and the United States. Work<strong>in</strong>g paper.<br />

Cohen, W. M., and Lev<strong>in</strong>thal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learn<strong>in</strong>g and<br />

<strong>in</strong>novation. Adm<strong>in</strong>istrative Science Quarterly, 35(1), 128-152.<br />

Comanor, W.S., and Scherer, F.M. (1969). Patent Statistics as a Measure of Technical Change. The<br />

Journal of Political Economy, 77(3), 392-398.<br />

Conley, T.G., and Ligon, E. (2002). Economic Distance and Cross-Country Spillovers. Journal of<br />

Economic Growth, 7(2), 157-87.<br />

David, P. (1992). Knowledge, property, and the system dynamics of technological change World Bank<br />

Research Observer, 7, 215.<br />

Deng, P. (2009). Why do Ch<strong>in</strong>ese firms tend to acquire strategic assets <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational expansion?<br />

Journal of World Bus<strong>in</strong>ess, 44(1), 74-84.<br />

Driffield, N., and Love, J. H. (2003). Foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestment, technology sourc<strong>in</strong>g and reverse<br />

spillovers. The Manchester School, 71(6), 659-672.<br />

Dunn<strong>in</strong>g, J. (1981). Expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>ternational direct <strong>in</strong>vestment position of countries: Towards a<br />

dynamic or developmental approach. Review of World Economics, 117(1), 30-64.<br />

Dunn<strong>in</strong>g, J. H. (2001). The eclectic (OLI) paradigm of <strong>in</strong>ternational production: Past, present and<br />

future. International Journal of the Economics of Bus<strong>in</strong>ess, 8(2), 173 - 190.<br />

Dunn<strong>in</strong>g, J., and Lundan, S. (2008). Institutions and the OLI paradigm of the mult<strong>in</strong>ational enterprise.<br />

Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 25(4), 573-593.<br />

Ethier, W. J. (1986). The <strong>Mult<strong>in</strong>ational</strong> Firm. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101(4), 805-834.<br />

Florida, R. (1997). The Globalization of R&D: Results of a Survey of Foreign-Affiliated R&D<br />

Laboratories <strong>in</strong> the USA. Research Policy, 26(1), 85-103.<br />

19


Fritsch, M. (2004). Cooperation and the efficiency of regional R&D activities. Cambridge Journal of<br />

Economics, 28(6), 829-846.<br />

Fu, X., Pietrobelli, C., and Soete, L. (2010). The Role of Foreign Technology and Indigenous<br />

Innovation <strong>in</strong> <strong>Emerg<strong>in</strong>g</strong> Economies: Technological Change and Catch<strong>in</strong>g Up. Inter-American<br />

Development Bank Technical Notes on Institutional Capacity and F<strong>in</strong>ance Sector No.<br />

IDB-TN-166.<br />

Girma, S., Gong, Y., and Görg, H. (2009). What Determ<strong>in</strong>es Innovation Activity <strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>ese<br />

State-Owned <strong>Enterprises</strong>? The Role of Foreign Direct Investment. World Development, 37(4),<br />

866-873.<br />

Globerman, S. (1979). Foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestment and 'spillover' efficiency benefits <strong>in</strong> Canadian<br />

manufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries. The Canadian Journal of Economics / Revue canadienne<br />

d'Economique, 12(1), 42-56.<br />

Globerman, S. and Chen, V.Z. (2010). Best Policy Practices for Promot<strong>in</strong>g Inward and Outward<br />

Foreign Direct Investment. The Conference Board of Canada Report: Ottawa, Canada.<br />

Globerman, S., Shapiro, D., and V<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g, A. (2005). Clusters and <strong>in</strong>tercluster spillovers: their <strong>in</strong>fluence<br />

on the growth and survival of Canadian <strong>in</strong>formation technology firms. Industrial and<br />

Corporate Change, 14(1), 27-60.<br />

Godfrey, L. G., McAleer, M., and McKenzie, C. R. (1988). Variable Addition and Lagrange Multiplier<br />

Tests for L<strong>in</strong>ear and Logarithmic Regression Models. The Review of Economics and Statistics,<br />

70(3), 492-503.<br />

Görg, H. Strobl, E. and Walsh, F. (2005). Why Do Foreign-Owned Firms Pay More? The Role of<br />

On-The-Job Tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g. Review of World Economics, 143(3), 464-482.<br />

Gornik-Tomaszewski, S., and Millan, M. A. (2005). Account<strong>in</strong>g for Research and Development Costs:<br />

A Comparison of U.S. and International Standards. Review of Bus<strong>in</strong>ess, 26(2), 42-47.<br />

Grabowski, H. G. (1968). The determ<strong>in</strong>ants of <strong>in</strong>dustrial research and development: A study of the<br />

chemical, drug, and petroleum <strong>in</strong>dustries. The Journal of Political Economy, 76(2), 292-306.<br />

Greene, W. (2004). Fixed effects and bias due to the <strong>in</strong>cidental parameters problem <strong>in</strong> the Tobit model.<br />

Econometric Reviews, 23(2), 125 - 147.<br />

Griffith, R., Redd<strong>in</strong>g, S., and Reenen, J. V. (2003). R&D and absorptive capacity: Theory and<br />

empirical evidence. The Scand<strong>in</strong>avian Journal of Economics, 105(1), 99-118.<br />

Griliches, Z. (1984). R&D, patents, and productivity. London.: University of Chicago Press.<br />

Griliches, Z. (1992). The search for R&D Spillovers. The Scand<strong>in</strong>avian Journal of Economics, 94,<br />

29-47.<br />

Grünfeld, L., and Sanna-Randaccio, F. (2005). Greenfield Investment or Acquisition? Optimal<br />

Foreign Entry Mode with Knowledge Spillovers <strong>in</strong> A Cournot Game. Paper presented at the<br />

ETSG Seventh Annual Conference, University College Dubl<strong>in</strong>.<br />

Guellec, D., and de la Potterie, B. P. (2001). The Internationalisation of Technology Analysed with<br />

Patent Data. Research Policy, 30(8), 1253-1266.<br />

Haddad, M. and Harrison, A.E. (1993). Are There Positive Spillovers from Direct Foreign Investment?<br />

Evidence from Panel Data for Morocco. Journal of Development Economics, 42(1), 51-74.<br />

Hall, B.H. (1993). R&D Tax Policy dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1980s: Success or Failure? Tax Policy and the Economy,<br />

7, 1-35.<br />

Hall, D.T., and Mansfield, R. (1971). Organizational and Individual Response to External Stress.<br />

Adm<strong>in</strong>istrative Science Quarterly, 16(4), 533-547.<br />

20


Hansen, J.A. (1992). Innovation, Firm Size, and Firm Age. Small Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Economics, 4(1), 37-44.<br />

Hausman, J.A. (1978). Specification tests <strong>in</strong> econometrics. Econometrica, 46(6), 1251-1271.<br />

Hejazi, W., and Safarian, A. E. (1999). Trade, foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestment, and R&D spillovers. Journal<br />

of International Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Studies, 30(3), 491-511.<br />

Hennart, J.-F. (1988). A transaction costs theory of equity jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures. Strategic Management<br />

Journal, 9(4), 361-374.<br />

Horstmann, I., MacDonald, G.M., and Sliv<strong>in</strong>ski, A. (1985). Patents as Information Transfer<br />

Mechanism: To Patent or (Maybe) Not to Patent. The Journal of Political Economy, 93(5),<br />

837-858.<br />

Hoskisson, R. E., Eden, L., Lau, C. M., and Wright, M. (2000). Strategy <strong>in</strong> emerg<strong>in</strong>g economies. The<br />

Academy of Management Journal, 43(3), 249-267.<br />

Jaffe, A. B., Trajtenberg, M., and Henderson, R. (1993). Geographic localization of knowledge<br />

spillovers as evidenced by patent citations. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(3),<br />

577-598.<br />

Javorcik, B. S. (2004). Does foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong>crease the productivity of domestic firms? In<br />

search of spillovers through backward l<strong>in</strong>kages. The American Economic Review, 94(3),<br />

605-627.<br />

Jung, W.S., and Marshall, P.J. (1985). Exports, Growth and Causality <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries.<br />

Journal of Development Economics, 18(1), 1-12.<br />

Keller, W. (2002). Geographic Localization of International Technology Diffusion. The American<br />

Economic Review, 92(1), 120-142.<br />

Keller, W. (2004). International Technology Diffusion. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(3),<br />

752-782.<br />

Kogut, B., and Chang, S.J. (1991). Technological Capabilities and Japanese Foreign Direct Investment<br />

<strong>in</strong> the United States. Review of Economics and Statistics, 73(3), 401-413.<br />

Kogut, B., and Zander, U. (1993). Knowledge of the Firm and the Evolutionary Theory of the<br />

<strong>Mult<strong>in</strong>ational</strong> Corporation. Journal of International Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Studies, 24(4), 621-645.<br />

Koizumi, T., and Kopecky, K. J. (1977). Economic Growth, Capital Movements and the International<br />

Transfer of Technical Knowledge. Journal of International Economics, 7(1), 45-65.<br />

Kuemmerle, W. (1999). The Drivers of Foreign Direct Investment <strong>in</strong>to Research and Development:<br />

An Empirical Investigation. Journal of International Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Studies, 30(1), 1-24.<br />

Li, J., Chen, D., and Shapiro, D.M. (2010). Product Innovations <strong>in</strong> <strong>Emerg<strong>in</strong>g</strong> Economies: The Role of<br />

Foreign Knowledge Access Channels and Internal Efforts <strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>ese Firms. Management and<br />

Organization Review, 6(2), 243-266.<br />

Liu, X., and Buck, T. (2007). Innovation performance and channels for <strong>in</strong>ternational technology<br />

spillovers: Evidence from Ch<strong>in</strong>ese high-tech <strong>in</strong>dustries. Research Policy, 36(3), 355-366.<br />

Luo, Y., and Tung, R. L. (2007). International expansion of emerg<strong>in</strong>g market enterprises: A<br />

spr<strong>in</strong>gboard perspective. Journal of International Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Studies, 38(4), 481-498.<br />

Mak<strong>in</strong>o, S., Lau, C.-M., and Yeh, R.-S. (2002). Asset-Exploitation versus Asset-Seek<strong>in</strong>g: Implications<br />

for Location Choice of Foreign Direct Investment from Newly Industrialized Economies.<br />

Journal of International Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Studies, 33(3), 403-421.<br />

Mansfield, E. (1985). How rapidly does new <strong>in</strong>dustrial technology leak out? The Journal of Industrial<br />

Economics, 34(2), 217-223.<br />

Mansfield, E., and Romeo, A. (1980). Technology Transfer to Overseas Subsidiaries by U.S.-Based<br />

21


Firms. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 95(4), 737-750.<br />

Markusen, J. R. (2004). <strong>Mult<strong>in</strong>ational</strong> firms and the theory of <strong>in</strong>ternational trade. Cambridge, MA:<br />

MIT Press.<br />

Mathews, J.A. (2002). Dragon <strong>Mult<strong>in</strong>ational</strong>s: A New Model of Global Growth. Oxford University<br />

Press: New York.<br />

Mathews, J.A. (2006). Dragon <strong>Mult<strong>in</strong>ational</strong>s: New Players <strong>in</strong> 21st Century Globalization. Asia<br />

Pacific Journal of Management, 23(1), 5-27.<br />

Mathews, J. A., and Zander, I. (2007). The <strong>in</strong>ternational entrepreneurial dynamics of accelerated<br />

<strong>in</strong>ternationalisation. Journal of International Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Studies, 38(3), 387-403.<br />

Maurseth, P.B., and Verspagen, B. (2002). Knowledge spillovers <strong>in</strong> Europe: A patent citations<br />

analysis. Scand<strong>in</strong>avian Journal of Economics, 104(4), 531-545.<br />

McDonald, J. F., and Moffitt, R. A. (1980). The Uses of Tobit Analysis. The Review of Economics and<br />

Statistics, 62(2), 318-321.<br />

Meyer, K.E. and S<strong>in</strong>ani, E. (2009). When and Where Does Foreign Direct Investment Generate<br />

Positive Spillovers? A Meta-Analysis. Journal of International Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Studies, 40,<br />

1075-1094.<br />

Møen, J. (2005). Is Mobility of Technical Personnel a Source of R&D Spillovers? Journal of Labor<br />

Economics, 23(1), 81-114.<br />

Muller, E., and Zenker, A. (2001). Bus<strong>in</strong>ess services as actors of knowledge transformation: the role of<br />

KIBS <strong>in</strong> regional and national <strong>in</strong>novation systems. Research Policy, 30(9), 1501-1516.<br />

Ostrom, E. (2000). Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms. The Journal of Economic<br />

Perspectives, 14(3), 137-158.<br />

Owen-Smith, J. and Powell, W.W. (2004). Knowledge networks as channels and conduits: The effects<br />

of spillovers <strong>in</strong> the Boston biotechnology community. Organization Science, 15(1), 5-21.<br />

Ozkan, N. (2002). Effects of F<strong>in</strong>ancial Constra<strong>in</strong>ts on Research and Development Investment: An<br />

Empirical Investigation. Applied F<strong>in</strong>ancial Economics, 12(11), 827-834.<br />

Patel, P. and Pavitt, K. (1997). The Technological Competencies of the World's Largest Firms:<br />

Complex and Path-Dependence, but Not Much Variety. Research Policy, 26(2), 141-156.<br />

Peng, H. (2010). Ch<strong>in</strong>a's Indigenous Innovation Policy and Its Effect on Foreign Intellectual Property<br />

Rights Holders. K<strong>in</strong>g & Wood's IP Department Ch<strong>in</strong>a Law Insight Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper.<br />

Peng, M. W. (1997). Firm Growth <strong>in</strong> Transitional Economies: Three Longitud<strong>in</strong>al Cases From Ch<strong>in</strong>a,<br />

1989-96. Organization Studies, 18(3), 385.<br />

People’s Daily (2010). Shufu Li: Acqusition of Volvo, what did Geely get?<br />

Qu<strong>in</strong>tas, P., Lefrere, P., and Jones, G. (1997). Knowledge management: A strategic agenda. Long<br />

Range Plann<strong>in</strong>g, 30(3), 385-391.<br />

Rugman, A. (1985). Internalization is still a general theory of foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestment. Review of<br />

World Economics, 121(3), 570-575.<br />

Rui, H., and Yip, G. S. (2008). Foreign acquisitions by Ch<strong>in</strong>ese firms: A strategic <strong>in</strong>tent perspective.<br />

Journal of World Bus<strong>in</strong>ess, 43(2), 213-226.<br />

Saggi, K. (2002). Trade, Foreign Direct Investment, and International Technology Transfer: A Survey.<br />

World Bank Research Observer, 17(2), 191-235.<br />

Sakakibara, M. (2002). Formation of R&D Consortia: Industry and Company Effects. Strategic<br />

Management Journal, 23(11), 1033-1050.<br />

Schmidt, T. (2006). An empirical analysis of the effects of patents and secrecy of knowledge spillovers.<br />

22


ZEW Discussion Paper No. 06-048.<br />

Serapio, M.G. and Dalton, D.H. (1999). Globalization of Industrial R&D: An Exam<strong>in</strong>ation of Foreign<br />

Direct Investments <strong>in</strong> R&D <strong>in</strong> the United States. Research Policy, 28(2-3), 303-316.<br />

Shefer, D., and Frenkel, A. (2005). R&D, Firm Size and Innovation: An Empirical Analysis.<br />

Technovation, 25(1), 25-32.<br />

Sjöholm, F. (1996). International transfer of knowledge: The role of <strong>in</strong>ternational trade and geographic<br />

proximity. Review of World Economics, 132(1), 97-115.<br />

Song, J., Almeida, P., and Wu, G. (2003). Learn<strong>in</strong>g-by-Hir<strong>in</strong>g: When Is Mobility More Likely to<br />

Facilitate Interfirm Knowledge Transfer? Management Science, 48(4), 351-365.<br />

Spencer, D. (1965). An External Military Precence, Technological Transfer and Structural Change.<br />

Kyhlos, 18, 451-471.<br />

Thompson, P., and Fox-Kean, M. (2005). Patents Citations and the Geography of Knowledge<br />

Spillovers: A Reassessment. The American Economic Review, 95(1), 450-460.<br />

Tob<strong>in</strong>, J. (1958). Estimation of Relationships for Limited Dependent Variables. Econometrica, 26(1),<br />

24-36.<br />

Tolent<strong>in</strong>o, P.E. (1993). Technological Innovation and Third World <strong>Mult<strong>in</strong>ational</strong>s. Routledge:<br />

London and New York.<br />

Wesson, T. (1999). A Model of Asset-Seek<strong>in</strong>g Foreign Direct Investment Drive by Demand<br />

Conditions. Canadian Journal of Adm<strong>in</strong>istrative Sciences / Revue Canadienne des Sciences de<br />

l'Adm<strong>in</strong>istration, 16(1), 1-10.<br />

Williamson, O. E. (1979). Transaction-Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations.<br />

Journal of Law and Economics, 22(2), 233-261.<br />

Wooldridge, J. M. 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. Cambridge, MA:<br />

MIT Press.<br />

Yamakawa, Y., Peng, M.W., and Deeds, D.L. (2008). What Drives New Ventures to Internationalize<br />

from <strong>Emerg<strong>in</strong>g</strong> to <strong>Developed</strong> Economies? Entrepreurship Theory and Practice, 32(1), 59-82.<br />

Zhang, Y., Li, H., Li, Y., and Zhou, L-A. (2010). FDI Spillovers <strong>in</strong> an <strong>Emerg<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Market</strong>: The Role of<br />

Foreign Firms’ Country Orig<strong>in</strong> Diversity and Domestic Firms’ Absorptive Capacity. Strategic<br />

Management Journal, 31(9), 969-989.<br />

Zhao, M. (2006). Conduct<strong>in</strong>g R&D <strong>in</strong> Countries with Weak Intellectual Property Rights Protection.<br />

Management Science, 52(8), 1185-1199.<br />

23


* p


* p


Table 2<br />

Summary Statistics and Correlation Matrix<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16) (17)<br />

(1) Proprietary R&D activeness 1.00<br />

(2) Host 3SIC # of patent (mean) 0.21 1.00<br />

(3) Host 3SIC $ of R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments (mean) 0.10 0.20 1.00<br />

(4) Host 3SIC # of R&D employment (mean) 0.29 0.48 0.75 1.00<br />

(5) Host 3SIC # of patent (sum) 0.32 0.92 0.15 0.43 1.00<br />

(6) Host 3SIC $ of R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments (sum) 0.27 0.30 0.87 0.70 0.43 1.00<br />

(7) Host 3SIC # of R&D employment (sum) 0.41 0.52 0.67 0.92 0.62 0.81 1.00<br />

(8) Firm size 0.23 0.06 0.02 0.08 0.13 0.11 0.15 1.00<br />

(9) Firm age -0.05 -0.10 -0.06 -0.09 0.01 0.06 0.01 0.13 1.00<br />

(10) Firm current ratio -0.06 0.01 0.00 0.06 -0.01 -0.03 0.05 0.04 -0.01 1.00<br />

(11) Firm solvency ratio 0.06 -0.02 0.01 -0.01 -0.04 -0.03 -0.02 0.00 0.06 0.33 1.00<br />

(12) Home R&D environment 0.62 0.26 0.24 0.38 0.33 0.35 0.46 0.21 -0.03 -0.03 -0.03 1.00<br />

(13) Home market size -0.06 0.01 0.09 0.04 0.00 0.06 0.01 0.07 -0.15 0.03 -0.09 -0.12 1.00<br />

(14) Host market size 0.20 0.89 0.16 0.48 0.81 0.25 0.52 0.09 -0.06 0.03 -0.01 0.22 -0.01 1.00<br />

(15) Weighted geographic distance 0.02 0.36 0.08 0.28 0.43 0.24 0.40 0.21 0.10 0.03 -0.03 0.42 0.03 0.33 1.00<br />

(16) Home tax burden -0.02 0.15 0.10 0.16 0.21 0.20 0.24 -0.07 0.08 0.05 -0.03 0.20 -0.03 0.11 0.45 1.00<br />

(17) Common official language 0.01 0.29 0.12 0.26 0.32 0.22 0.36 0.14 0.22 0.06 -0.07 0.37 -0.05 0.26 0.54 0.46 1.00<br />

Number of obs. 1561 2721 2637 2170 2721 2637 2170 2550 2721 2551 2551 2630 2721 2721 2721 2721 2721<br />

Mean 7.71 0.84 7.81 5.96 0.87 8.58 6.85 2.44 1.43 2.24 47.70 6.15 3.27 3.33 2.13 30.96 0.24<br />

St. Dev. 2.42 0.07 1.76 2.25 0.08 1.98 2.58 0.60 0.30 4.12 26.62 2.75 0.03 0.04 0.08 5.92 0.37<br />

3


Independent Variable<br />

Table 3<br />

Panel Tobit Regression Results<br />

Measure 1 Measure 2 Measure 3<br />

Mean Sum Mean Sum Mean Sum<br />

1 2 3 4 5 6<br />

Host DM's technological resources (Lagged by 4 Years) 0.20*** 0.22*** 0.10* 0.11* -0.06 -0.05<br />

Control Variables<br />

Firm size 0.31*** 0.28*** 0.36*** 0.32*** 0.33*** 0.30***<br />

Firm age -0.53 -0.91* -1.04* -1.45*** -0.95* -1.30**<br />

Current ratio -0.51 -0.08 -12.36** -11.66** -11.92** -11.29**<br />

Solvency ratio -0.82* -0.74 -0.41 -0.39 -0.38 -0.36<br />

Home R&D environment 1.15*** 1.12*** 0.71*** 0.64*** 0.68*** 0.62***<br />

Home market size 0.45*** 0.37*** 0.54*** 0.43*** 0.53*** 0.49***<br />

Host market size -0.16 -0.11 -0.14 -0.12 -0.14 -0.11<br />

Weighted geographic distance -0.33 -0.50 -0.67** -0.81*** -0.58** -0.73**<br />

Home tax burden 0.79 0.38 0.77 0.22 0.25 -0.14<br />

Common official language -0.63 -0.76 0.39 0.43 0.42 0.42<br />

Constant -2.87 -0.06 -2.55 1.80 -1.74 0.58<br />

Sigma u 2.09*** 2.01*** 2.19*** 2.14*** 2.24*** 2.20***<br />

Sigma e 1.21*** 1.21*** 1.38*** 1.37*** 1.35*** 1.35***<br />

Year Dummy<br />

Home Dummy<br />

Host Dummy<br />

Statistics<br />

* p


Independent Variable<br />

Measure 1<br />

Table 4<br />

Robustness Check: Panel Tobit Regression Results us<strong>in</strong>g Measure 1<br />

Us<strong>in</strong>g Host-Measure Means Us<strong>in</strong>g Host-Measure Summations<br />

7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16<br />

(No lag) (Lag 1) (Lag 2) (Lag 3) (Lag 5) (No lag) (Lag 1) (Lag 2) (Lag 3) (Lag 5)<br />

Host DM's <strong>in</strong>dustry-level $value of R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments 0.46*** 0.29*** 0.27*** 0.22*** 0.21*** 0.46*** 0.29*** 0.29*** 0.25*** 0.22***<br />

Control Variables<br />

Firm size 0.26*** 0.23*** 0.20*** 0.18*** 0.36*** 0.25*** 0.22*** 0.19*** 0.16*** 0.31***<br />

Firm age -0.20 -0.44 -0.09 -0.30 -0.67 -0.83* -0.99* -0.60 -0.77 -1.02*<br />

Current ratio -7.58** -10.38*** -5.03 -3.27 6.47 -6.83* -9.77** -4.66 -2.90 6.79<br />

Solvency ratio -0.16 0.01 -0.50 -0.79* -1.08** -0.12 0.03 -0.44 -0.72* -1.01**<br />

Home R&D environment 2.30*** 1.74*** 1.60*** 1.45*** 0.98*** 2.22*** 1.61*** 1.55*** 1.42*** 0.96***<br />

Home market size 0.56*** 0.61*** 0.55*** 0.51*** 0.43** 0.23** 0.32*** 0.39*** 0.41*** 0.36***<br />

Host market size 0.34* 0.25 0.15 0.02 -0.21 0.35* 0.24 0.16 0.04 -0.14<br />

Weighted geographic distance -1.10*** -0.99*** -0.55 -0.37 -0.31 -1.26*** -1.11*** -0.74** -0.58* -0.47<br />

Home tax burden -3.18** -2.42* -0.86 -0.37 0.52 -4.09*** -3.24** -1.29 -0.71 0.04<br />

Common official language 0.31 0.58 -0.30 -0.46 -0.70 0.51 0.70 -0.42 -0.60 -0.84<br />

Constant -14.36** -12.07 -11.65 -7.53 -1.62 -3.23 -2.27 -5.60 -3.30 0.78<br />

Sigma u 2.03*** 2.13*** 2.08*** 2.13*** 2.23*** 1.98*** 2.07*** 1.96*** 2.01*** 2.17***<br />

Sigma e 2.00*** 1.78*** 1.52*** 1.32*** 1.04*** 2.00*** 1.79*** 1.52*** 1.32*** 1.04***<br />

Year Dummy<br />

Home Dummy<br />

Host Dummy<br />

Statistics<br />

Number of Firms 231 231 192 191 188 231 231 192 191 188<br />

Number of Left-Censored Observations 155 108 69 47 28 155 108 69 47 28<br />

Number of Observations 1559 1393 1188 1021 686 1559 1393 1188 1021 686<br />

Chi-Square 436.20 275.96 185.53 131.65 78.24 450.35 287.67 214.23 161.17 98.98<br />

P-Value 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00<br />

* p


Table 5<br />

Robustness Check: Panel Tobit Regression Results us<strong>in</strong>g Different Weights<br />

(Estimates for <strong>in</strong>dependent variables only)<br />

Host Measures Weighted by Host GDP Host Measures Weighted by Distance<br />

(No lag) (Lag 1) (Lag 2) (Lag 3) (Lag 4) (Lag 5) (No lag) (Lag 1) (Lag 2) (Lag 3) (Lag 4) (Lag 5)<br />

Host DM's <strong>in</strong>dustry-level $ value of R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments 0.51*** 0.32*** 0.30*** 0.25*** 0.22*** 0.23*** 0.23*** 0.23*** 0.24*** 0.15** 0.12* 0.11*<br />

Host DM's <strong>in</strong>dustry-level # of R&D employment 0.74*** 0.48*** 0.43*** 0.35*** 0.31*** 0.31*** 0.32*** 0.33*** 0.34*** 0.22** 0.16* 0.16*<br />

Host DM's <strong>in</strong>dustry-level number of patents -0.13 -0.12 -0.12 -0.15 -0.07 -0.03 -0.12 -0.15 -0.16 -0.21 -0.1 -0.05<br />

* p

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!