26.01.2014 Views

Final documentation of the CGERegEU+ model

Final documentation of the CGERegEU+ model

Final documentation of the CGERegEU+ model

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Common Agricultural Policy Regional Impact – The Rural Development Dimension<br />

Collaborative project - Small to medium-scale focused research project under <strong>the</strong> Seventh Framework Programme<br />

Project No.: 226195<br />

WP3.2 Model development and adaptation – Regional CGEs<br />

Deliverable: D3.2.3<br />

<strong>Final</strong> <strong>documentation</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>CGERegEU+</strong> <strong>model</strong><br />

DRAFT VERSION<br />

Hannu Törmä, Katarzyna Zawalinska<br />

University <strong>of</strong> Helsinki, Ruralia Institute<br />

August 31 st , 2011<br />

1


Contents<br />

1 Introduction .................................................................................................................................. 3<br />

2 Additions to <strong>the</strong> base <strong>model</strong> ......................................................................................................... 3<br />

2.1 Dixon-Parmenter-Sutton-Vincent (DPSV) investment rule .................................................. 3<br />

2.2 Balance <strong>of</strong> payment equations (EU co-financing <strong>of</strong> RD measures) ...................................... 6<br />

3 Closures ........................................................................................................................................ 8<br />

3.1 Automatic (technical) closure in Tablo ................................................................................. 8<br />

3.2 Changes to <strong>the</strong> automatic closure ........................................................................................ 10<br />

3.2.1 Swaps proposed in <strong>the</strong> closure ..................................................................................... 12<br />

4 Modelling <strong>of</strong> RD measures ........................................................................................................ 12<br />

4.1 Variables and shocks ........................................................................................................... 13<br />

4.1.1 Modelling investments in human capital ..................................................................... 13<br />

4.1.2 Subsidies for investments in physical capital .............................................................. 14<br />

4.1.3 Direct income transfers ................................................................................................ 15<br />

4.1.4 Land subsidies .............................................................................................................. 15<br />

4.1.5 Subsidies for non-agricultural services in rural areas .................................................. 16<br />

4.2 Parameterization <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> shocks ............................................................................................ 16<br />

4.2.1 Shocks for investment in human capital ...................................................................... 16<br />

4.2.2 Shocks for investments in physical capital .................................................................. 16<br />

4.2.3 Shocks for direct income transfers ............................................................................... 17<br />

4.2.4 Shocks for land subsidies ............................................................................................. 17<br />

4.2.5 Shocks for non-agricultural services in rural areas ...................................................... 17<br />

5 Running <strong>the</strong> base <strong>model</strong> in GEMPACK .................................................................................... 18<br />

5.1 GEMPACK sub-programs .................................................................................................. 18<br />

5.2 Simulation setup in RunGEM ............................................................................................. 19<br />

6 Conclusions and summary ......................................................................................................... 21<br />

7 List <strong>of</strong> measures under 2007-2013 RDPs .................................................................................. 22<br />

8 Bibliography............................................................................................................................... 23<br />

2


1 Introduction<br />

This paper documents how to use <strong>the</strong> CGERegEU <strong>model</strong> to simulate <strong>the</strong> Pillar II measures at <strong>the</strong><br />

NUTS 2 level for EU27+ countries. It starts with <strong>the</strong> update on <strong>the</strong> latest <strong>model</strong>‟s development after<br />

<strong>the</strong> deliverable D.3.2.2. The most recent additions concern two aspects: improving <strong>the</strong><br />

characteristics <strong>of</strong> investments (i.e. introducing quasi dynamics in <strong>the</strong> comparative static <strong>model</strong>) and<br />

featuring <strong>the</strong> external co-financing from <strong>the</strong> EU budget for <strong>the</strong> Pillar II measures (i.e. adding<br />

balance <strong>of</strong> payment equations). Fur<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> paper explains: <strong>the</strong> possible choices for <strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong>‟s<br />

closures – depending on <strong>the</strong> policy focus (e.g. short run vs. long run, etc.). It also explains <strong>the</strong><br />

simulation design <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> RD measures in terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> variables and shocks implemented. Then it<br />

includes a short manual on how to use <strong>the</strong> GEMPACK s<strong>of</strong>tware in order to actually run <strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong><br />

and produce robust results on <strong>the</strong> regional impact <strong>of</strong> Pillar II measures. The paper ends with<br />

summary and conclusions as well as with <strong>model</strong> coding and electronic version <strong>of</strong> all essential files<br />

needed to run <strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong>.<br />

2 Additions to <strong>the</strong> base <strong>model</strong><br />

In D3.2.2 we added four new features into <strong>the</strong> base <strong>model</strong>. They are: <strong>the</strong> land factor, different real<br />

wage <strong>the</strong>ories, <strong>the</strong> Stone-Geary utility function (instead <strong>of</strong> Cobb-Douglas) and public sector<br />

accounting. Thanks to <strong>the</strong>se additions we have now three primary production factors: labour,<br />

capital, and land. Besides, now we can experiment with different wage <strong>the</strong>ories: sticky wages,<br />

adjusted Phillips curve or Wage curve based real wages. The Cobb-Douglas utility function has<br />

been replaced with <strong>the</strong> Stone-Geary leading to Linear Expenditure System, which is more<br />

sophisticated. Public sector accounting shows <strong>the</strong> tax revenues collected, and transfers given.<br />

Comparing to <strong>the</strong> second deliverable two new features have been added to <strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong>. First, <strong>the</strong><br />

investment rule allowing investment demands to be industry specific and endogenous, even if <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>model</strong> is still comparative static in its nature. Second, balance <strong>of</strong> payment equations were<br />

introduced to allow taking into account <strong>the</strong> external EU co-financing <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Pillar II measures from<br />

<strong>the</strong> EARDF budget.<br />

2.1 Dixon-Parmenter-Sutton-Vincent (DPSV) investment rule<br />

Up till now investments have been exogenous. For our purposes, it is better to use a more advanced<br />

investment rule, which is called DPSV (Dixon, Parmenter, Sutton, and Vincent, 1982, cp. 19).<br />

According to this <strong>the</strong>ory, investments made during a year can affect <strong>the</strong> capital stock <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> same<br />

year. We begin by presenting a conventional investment-capital stock flow mechanism. Small<br />

letters indicate percentage changes.<br />

xcap 1 = xinv 1 + (1 – δ) xcap 0 (all i, r)<br />

xcap 0 and xcap 1 refer to <strong>the</strong> capital stock at <strong>the</strong> beginning and end <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> same year, xinv 1 is<br />

investment or creation <strong>of</strong> new capital goods during <strong>the</strong> year, and δ is <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> depreciation, wear<br />

3


and tear <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> capital stock. The new capital goods xinv 1 are assumed to be produced according to<br />

<strong>the</strong> Leontief structure from domestic inputs.<br />

The only things that affect <strong>the</strong> capital stock at <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> one year are <strong>the</strong> current capital stock,<br />

depreciation and investment. It is thus assumed that <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> past investment decisions are<br />

fully incorporated in <strong>the</strong> current capital stock.<br />

The <strong>the</strong>ory do not attempt to explain total investments, only how this investment is allocated across<br />

using industries after a change in economic conditions. It is assumed that <strong>the</strong>re is an existing macro<br />

economic policy that determines <strong>the</strong>ir size.<br />

The current gross rate <strong>of</strong> return on fixed capital in a sector, gret is defined as <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> capital<br />

rent, pcap and <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> a unit <strong>of</strong> investment, pinv. Net rate <strong>of</strong> return is received by subtracting <strong>the</strong><br />

rate <strong>of</strong> depreciation <strong>of</strong> capital.<br />

gret = pcap - pinv<br />

nret = gret - δ<br />

(all i,r)<br />

The gross rate <strong>of</strong> return or pr<strong>of</strong>itability will increase (decrease) if <strong>the</strong> capital rent increases<br />

(decreases) more (less) than investment costs. Increasing pr<strong>of</strong>itability implies that <strong>the</strong> firms are<br />

earning more capital income than <strong>the</strong>y pay as investment costs. We fur<strong>the</strong>r assume that capital in a<br />

sector takes one year to install.<br />

Investors are assumed to be cautious in assessing <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> expanding <strong>the</strong> capital stock in a<br />

sector. They behave as if <strong>the</strong>y expect that sector‟s rate <strong>of</strong> return schedule in one year‟s time have<br />

<strong>the</strong> following form.<br />

gret 1 = gret 0 - β (xcap 1 - xcap 0 )<br />

(all i,r)<br />

0 and 1 represent <strong>the</strong> situation at <strong>the</strong> beginning and end <strong>of</strong> same year, and β is a positive parameter.<br />

The schedule is in <strong>the</strong> following figure.<br />

4


Figure 1 Expected rate <strong>of</strong> return schedule for a sector (Dixon et al., 1982)<br />

The horizontal axis measures <strong>the</strong> difference between <strong>the</strong> future and current capital stocks, measured<br />

as percentage points. The vertical axis shows <strong>the</strong> expected rate <strong>of</strong> return. If <strong>the</strong> capital stock were<br />

maintained at <strong>the</strong> existing level, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> expected rate <strong>of</strong> return would be <strong>the</strong> current rate <strong>of</strong> return,<br />

gret 0 . However, if investment plans were set so that xcap 1 – xcap 0 would reach <strong>the</strong> level A, <strong>the</strong>n<br />

businessmen would behave as if <strong>the</strong>y espected <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> return to fall to B.<br />

Now we assume that total investment expenditure, xinv_ir is allocated across industries so as to<br />

equate <strong>the</strong> expected rates <strong>of</strong> return. This means that <strong>the</strong>re exists some rate <strong>of</strong> return ω such that<br />

-β (xcap 1 - xcap 0 ) gret 0 = ω (all i,r)<br />

The gross growth rate <strong>of</strong> capital, ggro in a sector increases (decreases) if <strong>the</strong> gross rate <strong>of</strong> return <strong>of</strong><br />

that sector is larger (smaller) than <strong>the</strong> economy-wide rate <strong>of</strong> return ω. This indicates that<br />

investments grom faster that <strong>the</strong> capital stock within one year.<br />

ggro = xinv – xcap<br />

(all i,r)<br />

After substitutions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> above equations we get an equation for <strong>the</strong> gross growth rate <strong>of</strong> capital.<br />

ggro = finv + 0.33 (2.0 gret – invslack)<br />

(all i,r)<br />

finv is a shifter to enforce DSPV investment rule, 0.33 is 1/β, 2.0 is <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> gross to net rate <strong>of</strong><br />

return and invslack corresponds to ω, <strong>the</strong> exogenous economy-wide rate <strong>of</strong> return. It is to be<br />

interpreted as a risk related relationship with relatively fast- (slow-) growing industries requiring<br />

premia (accepting discounts) on <strong>the</strong>ir rates <strong>of</strong> return. According to Horridge (2003) attempts to<br />

improve <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>ory by updating <strong>the</strong>se parameter values have been found to occasionally lead to<br />

perversely signed coefficients.<br />

5


Considering <strong>the</strong> conventional investment-capital stock flow mechanism (see above), total<br />

investment expenditure is as follows.<br />

xinv_ir = ∑ i,r pinv xinv<br />

(all i,r)<br />

The DPSV rule relates for most sectors <strong>the</strong> investment <strong>of</strong> each sector to pr<strong>of</strong>itability in that sector.<br />

The effect is that sectors which become more pr<strong>of</strong>itable attract more investment. In some sectors,<br />

like in those where investment is determined by government policy, this rule might be<br />

inappropriate. In <strong>the</strong>se sectors investments are not mainly driven by current pr<strong>of</strong>its, like in<br />

education, administration etc. For this kind <strong>of</strong> sectors, it is better to let investment follow aggregate<br />

investment or national/regional trend (Horridge, 2003).<br />

2.2 Balance <strong>of</strong> payment equations (EU co-financing <strong>of</strong> RD measures)<br />

Since Pillar II measures are at least partly financed by EU (usually 75% to 80%) we need to take it<br />

into account in our <strong>model</strong> because <strong>the</strong> outcomes <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> policy differ depending on <strong>the</strong> source <strong>of</strong> its<br />

financing (domestic vs. foreign financing). If <strong>the</strong> policy is fully financed domestically, <strong>the</strong> spending<br />

has to be covered through savings/earnings obtained elsewhere in <strong>the</strong> domestic economy (e.g. from<br />

increased government revenues from higher taxes). It is different if <strong>the</strong> financing comes from<br />

outside <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy, from abroad (e.g. EU budget 1 ) <strong>the</strong>n it affects <strong>the</strong> country‟s position vis-avis<br />

<strong>the</strong> rest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> world. Hence it affects <strong>the</strong> Balance <strong>of</strong> payments (BOP) accounts, which is a<br />

record <strong>of</strong> all monetary transactions between a country and <strong>the</strong> rest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> world.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> long run, all components <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> BOP accounts must sum to zero with no overall surplus or<br />

deficits because all debts have to be paid. Thus, <strong>the</strong> current account on one side and <strong>the</strong> capital and<br />

financial account on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r should balance each o<strong>the</strong>r out. When an economy, however, has<br />

positive capital and financial accounts (a net financial inflow), <strong>the</strong> country's debits are more than its<br />

credits (due to an increase in liabilities to o<strong>the</strong>r economies or a reduction <strong>of</strong> claims in o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

countries). This is usually in parallel with a current account (trade) deficit; an inflow <strong>of</strong> money<br />

means that <strong>the</strong> return on an investment is a debit on <strong>the</strong> current account. Thus, <strong>the</strong> economy is using<br />

world savings to meet its local investment and consumption demands. It is a net debtor to <strong>the</strong> rest <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> world. This is <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> co-financing <strong>of</strong> RD measures, where <strong>the</strong> contributions from <strong>the</strong><br />

European Agricultural Fund for Rural Development (EAFRD) are counted as capital inflows. That<br />

is why we allow in <strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong> <strong>the</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> trade (BOT) moving towards <strong>the</strong> deficit by <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> EAFRD contributions to Pillar II measures, in order to counterbalance BOP.<br />

The following variables and equations were added to <strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong> in order to take account <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> BOP<br />

balancing:<br />

1 Of course it has not to be forgotten that countries pay contributions to <strong>the</strong> EU budget anyway, and some are net<br />

creditors while o<strong>the</strong>r are net debtors towards <strong>the</strong> CAP policy in general.<br />

6


Balance <strong>of</strong> trade is <strong>the</strong> difference between <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> total exports and imports to/from <strong>the</strong> rest <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> world (ROW).<br />

BOT = ∑ r VROWEXPtot - ∑ r VROWIMPtot<br />

The ratio <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> BOT to <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> expenditure side GDP is <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> following form.<br />

R_BOT_GDP = BOT / ∑ r GDPEXP<br />

The percentage change in <strong>the</strong> BOT, d_bot is defined as follows.<br />

100 * d_bot = ∑ r VROWEXPtot* (xrowexp_cr + prowexp_cr)<br />

- ∑ r VROWIMPtot* (xrowimp_cr + prowimp_cr)<br />

xrowexp_cr and xrowimp_cr are percentage changes <strong>of</strong> national exports, and prowexp_cr and<br />

prowimp_cr are <strong>the</strong> corresponding prices. The variables on <strong>the</strong> paren<strong>the</strong>s are endogenous, so d_bot<br />

will change according to <strong>the</strong>ir adjustment.<br />

The percentage change in <strong>the</strong> BOT/GDP ratio depends on:<br />

(100 / R_BOT_GDP) * d_bot_gdp = (100 / BOT) * d_bot – wgdpexp_r<br />

Here wgdpexp_r is national nominal expenditure side GDP.<br />

It is important to mention that in case <strong>of</strong> inflow <strong>of</strong> euros to <strong>the</strong> economies which have o<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

euro currencies (e.g. zloty in Poland, koruna in Czech Republic, etc.) <strong>the</strong> inflow makes a pressure<br />

on appreciation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> domestic currencies (prowimp), since euro have to be exchanged into<br />

national currency which increases <strong>the</strong> demand for it.<br />

Taking into account external co-financing from EARDF requires establishing <strong>the</strong> following shock<br />

statement in <strong>the</strong> command file:<br />

Shock d_bot = - x;<br />

where x equals to amount <strong>of</strong> co-financing from EARDF in mln <strong>of</strong> national currency. As explained<br />

before, <strong>the</strong> shock is negative, because percentage change <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> trade (d_bot) has to be<br />

put into deficit in order to counterbalance <strong>the</strong> financial inflows.<br />

7


3 Closures<br />

One important feature <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> base <strong>model</strong> implemented in <strong>the</strong> GEMPACK s<strong>of</strong>tware is its ability to<br />

set up closures specific for each policy simulations which can be changed (adjusted) in order to<br />

reflect <strong>the</strong> reality in <strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong> well as possible. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong> choice <strong>of</strong> closure in CGE <strong>model</strong><br />

determines <strong>the</strong> choice <strong>of</strong> macroeconomic <strong>the</strong>ory used in simulation and also decides about <strong>the</strong><br />

causalities leading to <strong>the</strong> particular results (Taylor i von Arnim, 2007]. Technically <strong>the</strong> closure <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong> for a particular simulation specified which variables are exogenous (that is, <strong>the</strong>ir values<br />

are given as shocks are unchanged in levels) and which variables are endogenous (that is, <strong>the</strong><br />

variable calculated when <strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong> is solved).<br />

3.1 Automatic (technical) closure in Tablo<br />

Technically, <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> endogenous variables in a CGE <strong>model</strong> must equal <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong><br />

equations. For complex <strong>model</strong>s with thousands <strong>of</strong> equations and variables having various<br />

dimensions (multi regions, sectors, factors, etc.) it is a very demanding task to find a sensible<br />

closure, which satisfies this accounting restriction. That is why GEMPACK provides a technical<br />

check up and <strong>of</strong>fers a list <strong>of</strong> all unmatched (without equations) variables which are most probably<br />

exogenous (<strong>the</strong> rest is assumed endogenous) 2 . The automatic closure for <strong>CGERegEU+</strong> is provided<br />

as follows.<br />

Table 1 Automatic closure for <strong>CGERegEU+</strong><br />

! Automatic closure generated by TABmate Tools...Closure command<br />

Variable / Dimension<br />

Exogenous acap ; ! IND*REG Capital-augmenting technical change<br />

Exogenous alab ; ! IND*REG Labor-augmenting technical change<br />

Exogenous aland ; ! IND*REG Land-augmenting technical change<br />

Exogenous aprim ; ! IND*REG Primary-factor-augmenting tech change<br />

Exogenous atot ; ! IND*REG All-input-augmenting technical change<br />

Exogenous<br />

Exogenous<br />

ahou_s ; ! COM*REG Taste change, househ. imp/dom composite<br />

fhou ; ! REG Reg. aver. propen. to cons. from disp income<br />

Exogenous delCAPTAXRATE ; ! IND*REG Change, capital tax rate<br />

Exogenous delHOUTAXRATE ; ! REG Tax rate, Arm and ROF goods to hou<br />

Exogenous delLABTAXRATE ; ! IND*REG Change, labour tax rate<br />

Exogenous delLANDTAXRATE ; ! IND*REG Change, land tax rate<br />

Exogenous delPRDTAXRATE ; ! IND*REG Change, prod tax rate<br />

Exogenous thouloc ; ! REG Local income tax rate<br />

Exogenous thoustate ; ! REG National income tax rate<br />

Exogenous fgov ; ! COM*GVT*REG Gov. demand shift variable<br />

Exogenous fgov_c ; ! GVT*REG Gov. demand shift variable<br />

Exogenous fgov_cgr ; ! 1 Gov. demand shift variable<br />

Exogenous fgov_cr ; ! GVT Gov. demand shift variable<br />

Exogenous fhou_r ; ! 1 Economy-wide shift on regional APCs<br />

Exogenous finv1 ; ! IND*REG Investment shift variable<br />

Exogenous flab ; ! IND*REG Real wage shifter<br />

2 Technically, authomatic closure is available from TABMATE in Tools/Tablo make code/Closure.<br />

8


Exogenous flab_i ; ! REG Real wage shifter<br />

Exogenous flab_ir ; ! 1 Real wage shifter<br />

Exogenous flab_r ; ! IND Real wage shifter<br />

Exogenous fstatehou ; ! REG Shifter-transf. from nat. gov to reg. hou.<br />

Exogenous fstateloc ; ! REG Shifter: transfers from nat. to reg. gov<br />

Exogenous fstateloc_r ; ! 1 Shifter: transfers from nat. to reg. gov<br />

Exogenous fxserr ; ! COM*REG Xserr shift variable<br />

Exogenous invslack ; ! 1 Invest. slack for exogenizing nat. invest<br />

Exogenous nhou ; ! REG Number <strong>of</strong> households<br />

Exogenous prowexp ; ! COM Price, exports to ROW, National currency<br />

Exogenous prowimp ; ! 1 Price <strong>of</strong> imports, National currency<br />

Exogenous xcap ; ! IND*REG Quantity <strong>of</strong> capital demanded<br />

Exogenous xhoutot ; ! REG Real Spending by households<br />

Exogenous xir<strong>of</strong> ; ! ROF*REG ROF goods used by investment<br />

Exogenous xirow ; ! REG ROW goods for investment<br />

Exogenous xland ; ! IND*REG Quantity <strong>of</strong> land (resource) demanded<br />

Rest endogenous; ! end <strong>of</strong> TABmate automatic closure<br />

The first block <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> exogenous variables (Table1) covers all technical change variables which are<br />

usually exogenous as in <strong>CGERegEU+</strong> (unless <strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong> has built in <strong>the</strong> endogenous growth <strong>the</strong>ory<br />

in it). There are several input-augmenting technical change variables for individual or grouped<br />

inputs, i.e. labor-augmenting technical change (alab), capital-augmenting technical change (acap),<br />

land-augmenting technical change (aland), and also combined input technical changes, i.e.primaryfactor-augmenting<br />

technical change (aprim) and all-input-augmenting technical change (atot). In<br />

case <strong>of</strong> all technical change variable, <strong>the</strong> negative shock means that <strong>the</strong> technology improved in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> particular input, so less <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> input is needed to obtain <strong>the</strong> same amount <strong>of</strong> output than<br />

before (<strong>the</strong> whole isoquant shifts).<br />

Apart from technical variables also <strong>the</strong> taste variable is included (ahou_s) and <strong>the</strong> propensity to<br />

consume which both are naturally set up outside <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong>, at least in <strong>the</strong> short run closure. The<br />

next block <strong>of</strong> exogenous variables consists <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> tax rates both indirect (on labour, land, capital,<br />

goods and production) and direct (local and national income tax). Since those variables are policy<br />

tools <strong>the</strong>y naturally come as exogenous in <strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong>.<br />

Ano<strong>the</strong>r exogenous block <strong>of</strong> variables covers a broad range <strong>of</strong> shifters. Shift variables are ones that<br />

are originally exogenous and <strong>the</strong>y are used in order to switch on or <strong>of</strong>f certain equations in order to<br />

choose which variant <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>ory we want to follow. For example in <strong>the</strong> labour market block <strong>the</strong>re<br />

is one real wage equation per wage <strong>the</strong>ory, with labour shifters. Three wage <strong>the</strong>ories <strong>of</strong>fer a choice<br />

between sticky wages in <strong>the</strong> short run vs fully adjustable nominal wages along wage curve (see <strong>the</strong><br />

equations explained in D3.2.2). There are real wage shifters (flab shifters) in all real wage <strong>the</strong>ories<br />

with different sectoral and regional dimensions. Consider <strong>the</strong> first <strong>the</strong>ory. When <strong>the</strong> shifters are<br />

exogenous <strong>the</strong>ir value will be zero. In this case nominal wage follow inflation, so real wage is<br />

sticky. The assumption is <strong>the</strong> third <strong>the</strong>ory where <strong>the</strong> change <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> unemployment rate and real<br />

wage are determined jointly. In similar fashion work o<strong>the</strong>r shifters - in equations for distribution <strong>of</strong><br />

government demand, for transfers from government to households, for exogenising national<br />

investment, etc.<br />

9


Fur<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> households is exogenous as well as reference prices (in national currency) -<br />

prowimp - price <strong>of</strong> imports (numeraire), and prowexp – price <strong>of</strong> exports. Their exogeneity comes<br />

from <strong>the</strong> small open economy assumption. Last but not least, <strong>the</strong> block <strong>of</strong> certain quantity variables<br />

is exogenous. They include: quantity <strong>of</strong> capital and land demanded, real spending by households<br />

(from LES), goods used by investment including imported goods to it.<br />

3.2 Changes to <strong>the</strong> automatic closure<br />

There is no unique or proper closure, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand closure needs to be justifiable. Basically<br />

<strong>the</strong>re are three reasons for which we alter <strong>the</strong> automatic closure: 1) to take account <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> time<br />

horizon <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> simulations (short vs. long run closure), 2) to take account <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> macroeconomic<br />

features <strong>of</strong> analysed economies (e.g. small open economy vs. big open economy), 3) to allow<br />

particular policy simulations.<br />

The typical short run closure in a comparative static <strong>model</strong> assumes that employment is endogenous<br />

while capital and land are exogenous. Wages in short run are usually assumed to be sticky - little<br />

responsiveness due to wage contracts, labour union negotiations, etc.. Rate <strong>of</strong> return on capital is<br />

endogenous. Trade balance is endogenous but <strong>the</strong> remaining composites <strong>of</strong> GDP expenditure side<br />

(private and public consumption) are exogenous (Figure 1).<br />

Figure 1 Typical causation in short-run closure in a comparative-static <strong>model</strong><br />

Source: OraniG course materials by CoPS, Monash University Melbourne Australia<br />

10


On <strong>the</strong> contrary <strong>the</strong> long run closure assumes that employment is exogenous (does not depend on<br />

policy but demographic determinants) and determines real wage. Capital stock is endogenous and<br />

depends on rate <strong>of</strong> return on capital. If DPSV (or o<strong>the</strong>r endogenization <strong>of</strong> investment rule) is<br />

included, <strong>the</strong>n sectoral investment follows capital. Land can be sometimes endogenous in <strong>the</strong> long<br />

run as well (if <strong>the</strong>re are some reserves in some types <strong>of</strong> land and if land supply is responsive to<br />

policy measures) or exogenous as usually it is a case. Trade balance is exogenous in long run while<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r elements <strong>of</strong> national absorption are endogenous (public and private consumption and<br />

investments).<br />

Figure 2 Typical causation in <strong>the</strong> long-run closure in a comparative-static <strong>model</strong><br />

Source: OraniG course materials by CoPS, Monash University Melbourne Australia<br />

Typically, macro-environment in <strong>the</strong> closure refers to macroeconomic determinants (<strong>the</strong>ories) for<br />

particular economies. It includes also relations <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy vis-a-vis <strong>the</strong> rest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> world. If <strong>the</strong><br />

economy is small it cannot affect <strong>the</strong> rest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> world prices, so price <strong>of</strong> exports and also price <strong>of</strong><br />

imports are exogenous. In <strong>the</strong> short run a country can run on deficit on <strong>the</strong> trade account which<br />

represents national dissaving, so balance <strong>of</strong> trade can be endogenous. However, no country can run<br />

<strong>the</strong> trade deficit constantly, so in <strong>the</strong> long run it is natural to fix <strong>the</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> trade so it becomes<br />

exogenous. Besides, if <strong>the</strong> policy is financed from abroad, <strong>the</strong> trade balance is affected so it is<br />

exogenised to be shocked by <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> external financing. Macro-environment can also<br />

specify which wage <strong>the</strong>ory is used (sticky wages or wage curve, etc.) and o<strong>the</strong>r economic <strong>the</strong>ories.<br />

11


Simulations can specifically require some exogenisation <strong>of</strong> certain variables to shock <strong>the</strong>m or<br />

endogenisation to see <strong>the</strong> effect on <strong>the</strong>m. For example in case <strong>of</strong> direct transfers to households (as in<br />

case <strong>of</strong> early retirement scheme) <strong>the</strong>y are initially endogenous but since we know <strong>the</strong> amounts<br />

transferred to <strong>the</strong>m we exogenise <strong>the</strong>m so to shock <strong>the</strong>m and <strong>the</strong>n see <strong>the</strong> policy effects.<br />

3.2.1 Swaps proposed in <strong>the</strong> closure<br />

All <strong>the</strong> changes to <strong>the</strong> automatic closure are done by swapping <strong>the</strong> initially exogenous variables<br />

with <strong>the</strong> presently endogenous ones. The following swaps are proposed for our simulations and as<br />

such are <strong>the</strong> part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> command file (below <strong>the</strong> automatic closure):<br />

1) Time horizon swaps<br />

! Long-run factor market closure<br />

swap xcap = fgret; ! Capital stock determined endogenously<br />

swap finv1 = ggro; ! Investment follows xcap<br />

swap flab_ir = xlab_ir; ! Total labour is exog. for demographic reasons<br />

2) Macro-environment swaps<br />

swap fgov = xgov; ! Government budget is fixed so <strong>the</strong> policy affects<br />

only <strong>the</strong> private sector<br />

swap d_bot = prowimp; !Foreign trade is in balance<br />

3) Policy swaps<br />

swap fhou = whou; !to enable direct income transfer as in <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong><br />

early retirement<br />

4 Modelling <strong>of</strong> RD measures<br />

There are more than 40 measures to be <strong>model</strong>led within RDP 2000-2006 and 2007-2013. In order to<br />

handle <strong>the</strong>m for all EU27+ NUTS2 regions we need to group <strong>the</strong>m. In D.3.2.1 we proposed 5 major<br />

categories <strong>of</strong> policy instruments subdivided into altoge<strong>the</strong>r 10 fairly homogeneous groups <strong>of</strong><br />

measures which can be simulated toge<strong>the</strong>r. Instruments in group 1 are subsidies for investments in<br />

human capital so <strong>the</strong>y increase productivity (not only labor productivity but also indirectly o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

factors‟ productivity) in ei<strong>the</strong>r agricultural or o<strong>the</strong>r services sector; instruments in group 2 are<br />

subsidies for investments in physical capital in such sectors as construction, agriculture, forestry,<br />

and food processing; group 3 ga<strong>the</strong>rs measures implemented in form <strong>of</strong> direct income transfers for<br />

individual farmers or groups <strong>of</strong> farmers (such as early retirement or young farmers‟ support under<br />

2000-2006 scheme); group 4 can be called compensatory aids and is granted in form <strong>of</strong> land<br />

subsidies ei<strong>the</strong>r in agricultural or forestry sector; group 5 combines measures aiming at increasing<br />

non-agricultural activities and outputs in rural areas, which are mainly materializing in a services<br />

12


sector (e.g. tourism, trade, transport, etc.). So <strong>the</strong>y are basically subsidies for non-agricultural<br />

services in rural areas.<br />

4.1 Variables and shocks<br />

For each group <strong>of</strong> policy measures <strong>the</strong>re is a different policy design. Please also refer to Table 3 in<br />

deliverable D.3.2.1.<br />

4.1.1 Modelling investments in human capital<br />

Among investments in human capital we distinguish two subgroups <strong>of</strong> measures, those which<br />

directly aim to improve human capital <strong>of</strong> farmers (or <strong>of</strong> agricultural sector) and those which aim to<br />

increase human capital (outside <strong>of</strong> agriculture) in rural areas.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> first group, improving human capital in agricultural sector, we would <strong>model</strong> <strong>the</strong> following<br />

measures: 111, 114, 115, 132, 133, 142, 143 and 331 (see list <strong>of</strong> measures in Annex 7.5). They are<br />

mostly related to improving labour productivity <strong>of</strong> farmers but also o<strong>the</strong>r types <strong>of</strong> productivity<br />

because farmers get more training and information also on how to use o<strong>the</strong>r inputs more effectively<br />

and efficiently.<br />

1) The proposed shocks are to total factor productivity in agricultural sector: atot (IND*REG):<br />

all-input-augmenting technical change, where IND would be “AGR” and REG all regions<br />

which have those measures. The value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> shock would be a percentage change between<br />

<strong>the</strong> TFP in initial situation and TFP after <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> all inputs toge<strong>the</strong>r are subsidied by <strong>the</strong><br />

amount <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> measure. This means that thanks to those measures <strong>the</strong> TFP increased because<br />

<strong>the</strong> inputs can be saved by <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> subsidy. So:<br />

,<br />

where Q(i,r) is <strong>the</strong> initial value <strong>of</strong> production in agricultural sector in certain region<br />

and I (i,r) is <strong>the</strong> initial value <strong>of</strong> all inputs used in agriculture in <strong>the</strong> region. Then, after<br />

<strong>the</strong> RDP measures are implemented to improve productivity <strong>of</strong> human capital in<br />

agricultural sector <strong>the</strong> total factor productivity it calculated as:<br />

.<br />

The value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> shock is <strong>the</strong> percentage change difference between <strong>the</strong> two, so:<br />

*100<br />

Example: If <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> agricultural production in certain region is 100 million and <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong><br />

total factor inputs to agriculture in this region is 80 million, <strong>the</strong>n TFP1 =100/80= 1.25. Then, if <strong>the</strong><br />

value <strong>of</strong> all measures related to human capital for agriculture in this region is let‟s say 20 million<br />

<strong>the</strong>n TFP2=100/(80-20)= 1.67. Then <strong>the</strong> shock value = (1.25-1.67)/1.67= -0,25. It means that we<br />

increase TFP in agriculture in certain region by 0,25% due to <strong>the</strong> RDP measures devoted to<br />

improving human capital productivity. See <strong>the</strong> next section for appropriate shock notation for <strong>the</strong><br />

command file.<br />

13


2) The second group <strong>of</strong> increasing human capital (outside <strong>of</strong> agriculture) include: 341, 411-<br />

413, 421, 431, 511. They are measures which aim at increasing <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> human capital<br />

and non-agricultural economy in rural areas. The difference to <strong>the</strong> first group is that <strong>the</strong><br />

former aimed at increasing productivity <strong>of</strong> human capital, while those measures aim to<br />

increase <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> human capital in rural areas by developing non-agricultural<br />

activities. That is why we propose to simulate it as a subsidy to capital 3 in non-agricultural<br />

sectors, and primarily in services. So <strong>the</strong> variable proposed to be shocked now is:<br />

delCAPTAXRATE (IND,REG) - which is a subsidy rate for capital in certain sectors in<br />

certain regions (or more precisely capital tax rate change 4 ). IND can be any <strong>of</strong> 10 remaining<br />

sectors outside <strong>of</strong> agriculture 5 depending on information which sectors are most stressed in<br />

LDSs <strong>of</strong> particular NUTS2 region. If it is believed to be small shops <strong>the</strong>n IND can be trade<br />

and transport sector (TTR), or if it is tourism one one can set up IND as hotels and<br />

restaurants (HOT) as a proxy. If <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> measures devoted to <strong>the</strong> human capital<br />

outside <strong>of</strong> agriculture (subsidy) in certain region is S (IND, REG) and <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> capital<br />

(depreciation plus operating surplus gross) in <strong>the</strong> region in this sector is C (IND, REG) <strong>the</strong>n:<br />

, where “-“ means that it is a subsidy.<br />

Example: If <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> all measures related to human capital outside <strong>of</strong> agriculture in certain<br />

region is 50 million (value <strong>of</strong> subsidy) and it is directed into a certain sector IND which value <strong>of</strong><br />

capital is 500, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> shock value = - 50/500= - 0.1. The same way for all regions in <strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong>.<br />

4.1.2 Subsidies for investments in physical capital<br />

Within <strong>the</strong> group <strong>of</strong> subsidies for investments in physical capital we distinguish three subgroups<br />

<strong>of</strong> measures: 1) those which support physical construction, 2) those which support agriculture and<br />

forestry potential, 3) those which support food processing.<br />

1) Among <strong>the</strong> measures granted in form <strong>of</strong> investments in physical capital which support<br />

constructions are: 112, 121, 131, 141, 321-323 (see list <strong>of</strong> measures in Annex 7.5). The<br />

proposed shock variable is a subsidy for capital in <strong>the</strong> construction sector, so <strong>the</strong> shock<br />

variable would be: delCAPTAXRATE (“CNS”, REG). The shock value in that case would<br />

be <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> RD measures mentioned above related to <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> capital in <strong>the</strong><br />

construction sector in each region.<br />

Example: If in a particular region, <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> all measures mentioned above would be 100 million<br />

and <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> capital in <strong>the</strong> construction sector would be 500 million, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> shock value =<br />

-100/500 = - 0.20. See section 4.2.2.<br />

2) Among <strong>the</strong> measures which support agricultural potential/capital directly are: 122, 124, 125,<br />

126. So <strong>the</strong> proposed shock variable is a subsidy for capital in ei<strong>the</strong>r agricultural sector or<br />

3 Our <strong>model</strong> has physical and human capital treated toge<strong>the</strong>r so it is impossible to subsidise only human capital part <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> total capital.<br />

4 In <strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong>‟s code convention subsidies are expressed as taxes with negative signs.<br />

5 As for reminding, <strong>the</strong> current database for CGERegEU27+ has aggregation to 11 sectors: (Agriculture (AGR),<br />

Forestry (FOR), O<strong>the</strong>r primary production (OPP), Food processing (FOP), Manufacturing (MAN), Energy (ENE),<br />

Construction (CNS), Trade and Transport (TTR), Hotels and Restaurants (HOT), O<strong>the</strong>r services(OSE). Generally <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>model</strong> can run with any number <strong>of</strong> sectors.<br />

14


forestry or combination <strong>of</strong> both, depending on <strong>the</strong> situation in particular region. So <strong>the</strong><br />

proposed shock variable is a subsidy for capital in agriculture and/or forestry, which in<br />

<strong>model</strong> notation is: delCAPTAXRATE (“AGR”, REG) and delCAPTAXRATE (“FOR”,<br />

REG). The values <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> shocks equal to <strong>the</strong> values <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> above RD measures related to<br />

values <strong>of</strong> Capital in Agriculture and Forestry, respectively.<br />

Example: If for particular region <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> above measures is 80 million and <strong>the</strong> capital in<br />

agricultural sector is 100 million, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> shock value = -80/100 = -0.8.<br />

3) Last type <strong>of</strong> measure in this category is subsidising investments in Food processing. Only<br />

one measure falls in <strong>the</strong> category, i.e. 123. This measure can be parametrisised analogically<br />

to <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r two categories, so we can treat is as a subsidy for capital in <strong>the</strong> food processing<br />

in each region, i.e. delCAPTAXRATE (“FOP”, REG). The value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> shock for each<br />

region will be <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> measure 123 related to <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> Capital in Food<br />

processing sector, analogically to <strong>the</strong> previous example.<br />

4.1.3 Direct income transfers<br />

All <strong>the</strong> measures which are directly paid to <strong>the</strong> farmers as a sort <strong>of</strong> income or pension (not as a<br />

reimbursement and not per hectare and without strict obligations on how it can be spent) are treated<br />

as direct transfers. Here we classify two measures 113 (early retirement) and also 112 (support for<br />

young farmers) in <strong>the</strong> scheme 2000-2006 (in 2007-2013 period <strong>the</strong> measure was changed into a<br />

simple investment scheme). We would <strong>model</strong> <strong>the</strong>se measures as an increase in households‟ nominal<br />

income, through variable wfacinc (REG) and <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> shock will be <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> above<br />

measures related to <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> factor income by regions. One could argue that apart from <strong>the</strong><br />

income effect also some productivity effect should be grasped. However, firstly it would require<br />

separate studies to assess whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> productivity effect is present and <strong>of</strong> which amount. In some<br />

cases <strong>the</strong> productivity may not occur in short time at all if a farmer transfers his agricultural<br />

activities to his family member (e.g. son) because in fact <strong>the</strong> land activated stay in <strong>the</strong> same family<br />

and <strong>the</strong> management <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> farm may also not change in reality.<br />

Example: If for a particular region <strong>the</strong> households‟ income from labour, land and capital<br />

endowments equals 20 000 millions, and <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> early measures 113 and 112 (2000-2006)<br />

equals 80 million <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> shock value = (80/20 000)*100 = 0.4. In order to take account <strong>of</strong> farmers<br />

households in <strong>the</strong> region, <strong>the</strong> shock can be scaled down by taking into account <strong>the</strong> share <strong>of</strong><br />

agricultural household income in total household income in <strong>the</strong> region.<br />

4.1.4 Land subsidies<br />

There are several measures which are paid per hectare and which are <strong>the</strong>refore perceived as land<br />

subsidies. We distinguish two groups <strong>of</strong> such measures, those related primarily to farm land (211-<br />

216, 22-225) and those related to forest land (221, 226). In both cases <strong>the</strong>y will be <strong>model</strong>led with<br />

variable related to land subsidies, i.e. delLNDTAXRATE (IND, REG), however in <strong>the</strong> former case<br />

IND will be AGR while in <strong>the</strong> latter industry will be FOR, i.e. delLNDTAXRATE (“AGR”, REG)<br />

and delLNDTAXRATE (“FOR”, REG). There seems not to be plans to include forest land into <strong>the</strong><br />

NUTS 2 SAMs, but this might change. The value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> shock will be calculated by relating <strong>the</strong><br />

value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> measures to <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> land (land rentals) from agricultural and forestry sectors, taken<br />

with negative sign (“-“ indicates subsidy).<br />

15


Example: If <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> measures paid per ha <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> farm land in a region is 50 million and <strong>the</strong><br />

value <strong>of</strong> land taxes paid in <strong>the</strong> region is 400 million <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> shock value = -50/400 = -0.125.<br />

4.1.5 Subsidies for non-agricultural services in rural areas<br />

Support for non agricultural economy in rural areas which does not include construction (<strong>the</strong> latter<br />

are in <strong>the</strong> category <strong>of</strong> investment subsidies) include axis 3 measures such as 311, 312, and 313.<br />

They are basically supporting development <strong>of</strong> certain service sectors (tourism, trade, etc.) and aim<br />

at increasing entrepreneurship in rural areas. Hence, in different regions <strong>the</strong>re can be different types<br />

<strong>of</strong> services supported, so we would <strong>model</strong> this as a production subsidy for various sectors:<br />

delPRDTAXRATE (IND, REG). Then if in a certain region those measures support small shop<br />

business <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> appropriate parametrization would be via delPRDTAXRATE(“TTR”, REG), if<br />

<strong>the</strong>y support mainly tourism, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> good proxy would be delPRDTAXRATE(“HOT”, REG), etc.<br />

The shock value would be <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> measures related to <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> production <strong>of</strong> those<br />

particular sectors in <strong>the</strong> regional economy taken with negative sign.<br />

Example: if in a certain region <strong>the</strong> measures 311, 312 went mainly to support opening small shops<br />

and 313 was devoted to support development <strong>of</strong> tourism, <strong>the</strong>n provided that <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> 311 and<br />

312 was 20 million, value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> trade sector in this region was 400 million, <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> measure<br />

313 was 10 million, and <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> hotels and restaurants sector would be 500 million, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong><br />

first shock value = -20/400 = -0.05 and this would be used to shock variable<br />

delPRDTAXRATE(“TTR”, REG). The second shock value = - 10 /500 = -0.02 would be used to<br />

shock variable delPRDTAXRATE(“HOT”, REG). See more options for parametrisation in <strong>the</strong> next<br />

session.<br />

4.2 Parameterization <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> shocks<br />

4.2.1 Shocks for investment in human capital<br />

Shock atot (“AGR”, REG) = - x ;<br />

where x is calculated for each region as follows: x = (TFP1 – TFP2)/TFP2*100<br />

and <strong>the</strong> formula for calculating TFPs are as follows: TFP1 = VACT2(AGR,r)/VPRIM1(AGR,r)<br />

and TFP2 = VACT2(“AGR”,REG)/[VPRIM1(“AGR”, REG) – Value <strong>of</strong> Measures (111, 114, 115,<br />

331, 132, 133 142, 331 in each region)]. VACT and VPRIM are <strong>the</strong> values <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Armington good<br />

(column sum in SAM) and total factor input to a sector (see D3.2.2, Figure 2).<br />

Shock delCAPTAXrate (“AGR”, REG) = -y;<br />

where values for y are calculated for each region as follows y = Value <strong>of</strong> Measures (341, 411-413,<br />

421, 431, 511) / VCAPPT(AGR,REG). Note that “-“means subsidy, while <strong>the</strong> same variable with<br />

“+” would mean tax. VCAPPT is <strong>the</strong> capital cost to <strong>the</strong> firm.<br />

4.2.2 Shocks for investments in physical capital<br />

Shock delCAPTAXrate (“CNS”, REG) = - z;<br />

where values for z are calculated for each region as follows z = Value <strong>of</strong> Measures (112, 121, 131,<br />

141, 321-323) / VCAPPT(CNS,REG).<br />

16


Shock delCAPTAXrate (“AGR”, REG) = - a;<br />

Shock delCAPTAXrate (“FOR”, REG) = - b;<br />

where values for z are calculated for each region as follows a = Value <strong>of</strong> Measures (122, 124, 125,<br />

126) / VCAPPT(AGR,REG) or b= Value <strong>of</strong> Measures (122, 124, 125, 126) / VCAPPT (FOR,<br />

REG).<br />

Shock delCAPTAXrate (“FOP”, REG) = - c;<br />

where values for c are calculated for each region as follows c = Value <strong>of</strong> Measure 123 /<br />

VCAPPT(“FOP”,REG).<br />

4.2.3 Shocks for direct income transfers<br />

swap fhou = wfacinc ! in order to exogenise nominal factor income <strong>of</strong> households by regions<br />

shock wfacinc (REG) = d;<br />

where values for d are calculated as follows d=Value <strong>of</strong> measures 113 and 112 6 /VFACINC (REG),<br />

where VFACINC is net factor income by region.<br />

4.2.4 Shocks for land subsidies<br />

shock delLNDTAXRATE(“AGR”, REG) = - e;<br />

where: e = Value <strong>of</strong> measures (211-216, 22-225) / VLANDPT(“AGR”,REG)<br />

shock delLNDTAXRATE(“FOR”, REG) = - f;<br />

where: f = Value <strong>of</strong> measures (221, 226) / VLANDPT(“FOR”,REG), where VLANDPT is <strong>the</strong> land<br />

cost to <strong>the</strong> firm.<br />

4.2.5 Shocks for non-agricultural services in rural areas<br />

shock delPRDTAXRATE (IND, REG) = -g;<br />

where: IND can be any sector except agriculture and forestry, so IND = OPP, FOP, ENE, MAN ,<br />

CNS, TTR, HOT or OSE; g = value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> measures (311,312, 313) / VCOST (IND, REG), where<br />

VCOST is input cost <strong>of</strong> a sector excluding production taxes.<br />

6 Measure 112 was granted only in <strong>the</strong> budgetary period 2000-2006 in form <strong>of</strong> direct income support, in 2007-2013 it<br />

was ra<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> subsidy in physical investments.<br />

17


5 Running <strong>the</strong> base <strong>model</strong> in GEMPACK<br />

5.1 GEMPACK sub-programs<br />

GEMPACK is a general purpose package for CGE <strong>model</strong>s and is not <strong>model</strong> specific. It is not a<br />

single program, but consists <strong>of</strong> a group <strong>of</strong> sub-programs, among which <strong>the</strong> most important ones are:<br />

ViewHAR - a Windows program for viewing data files (.HAR files)<br />

ViewSOL - a Windows program for viewing solution files (.sl4 files)<br />

WinGEM - provides an environment for carrying out <strong>model</strong>ling and associated tasks.<br />

RunGEM - provides an environment for carrying out simulations with a fixed <strong>model</strong><br />

TABmate - editor for TABLO Input files used for creating and modifying <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> a <strong>model</strong><br />

and also command files (.TAB and .CMF files)<br />

AnalyseGE – a Windows program used for analysing simulation results<br />

RunDynam – Windows interfaces for running recursive dynamic <strong>model</strong>s<br />

The sub-programs work with different files. The summary <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> files and programs are presented in<br />

Table 2.<br />

Table 2 Summary <strong>of</strong> GEMPACK files<br />

Source: Harrison W. J. and Pearson K. R. (2002). GEMPACK Documentation No. GPD-1<br />

18


5.2 Simulation setup in RunGEM<br />

In order to avoid confusion with use <strong>of</strong> various GEMPACK sub-programs, we explain how to carry<br />

out simulations with use <strong>of</strong> only RunGEM. This program leads <strong>the</strong> user through all <strong>the</strong> stages <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

simulation process, starting with choice <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong>, data, closure, shocks, and <strong>the</strong>n leads to<br />

output, solution and result files as shown in Picture 1.<br />

Picture 1: Simulation process in RunGEM<br />

Source: The RunGEM programme by Monash University<br />

The steps are <strong>the</strong> following (all required files are included in an email containing also D3.2.3):<br />

1. We choose MODEL which is an .exe file with <strong>model</strong> (Regfin_for_CAPRI.exe) and <strong>the</strong><br />

DATA file (Regfin_for_CAPRI.HAR)<br />

2. Then we choose CLOSURE file (Regfin_for_CAPRI_LR.CLS) which has apart from<br />

automatically generated closure also all amendments to take account <strong>of</strong> long-run and <strong>of</strong> our<br />

macro-environment so it has all swaps (described in <strong>the</strong> previous section) already indicated<br />

but not shocks yet. One can also manually paste <strong>the</strong> closure in <strong>the</strong> box <strong>of</strong>fered <strong>the</strong>re by<br />

copying <strong>the</strong> contents <strong>of</strong> Table 1 above and swaps from section 3.2.1.<br />

3. The next step is a specification <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> SHOCKS. As we described above, for each group <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> policy instruments <strong>the</strong> shocks are different. The RunGEM programme make <strong>the</strong> choice<br />

for shock variables easy because in <strong>the</strong> window “Variable to shock” it <strong>of</strong>fers all variables<br />

which are exogenous at <strong>the</strong> moment. Besides apart from <strong>the</strong>ir short names it <strong>of</strong>fers full<br />

names <strong>of</strong> selected variables and reminds <strong>the</strong>ir dimensions. Then <strong>the</strong> program prompts you to<br />

select <strong>the</strong> “Elements to be shocked“, i.e. you can choose sectors (all or particular) or regions<br />

(all or selected ones), etc. Then it asks about <strong>the</strong> values <strong>of</strong> shocks. Those have to be<br />

calculated in a separate spreadsheet according to <strong>the</strong> formulas presented in Section 4.2.<br />

After <strong>the</strong> specification is ready you click “Add to shock list“. The shock statements can also<br />

19


e copied (as <strong>the</strong>y are presented in section 4.2) and pasted into <strong>the</strong> box <strong>of</strong>fered <strong>the</strong>re. One<br />

can have prepared shocks for each group <strong>of</strong> measures as separate files and <strong>the</strong>n only choose<br />

<strong>the</strong> appropriate file for particular simulation. The programme also reminds <strong>the</strong> correct<br />

syntax for <strong>the</strong> shock statement as you proceed.<br />

4. In next step we specify <strong>the</strong> names <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> output (post simulation) files. The following syntax<br />

is an example:<br />

Solution file = “investment subsidies”;<br />

Updated file INFILE = “investment subsidies.upd”;<br />

File SUMMARY= “investment subsidies.ou1”;<br />

5. In next step one makes a choice <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> solution method in folder SOLVE. There are<br />

basically four choices <strong>of</strong>fered: Johansen, Euler, Gragg and Midpoint. The differences as<br />

well as pros and cons <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> methods are discussed in <strong>the</strong> GEMPACK manual in details but<br />

we recommend <strong>the</strong> following: Gragg 3 solutions in 6 steps, Sub-interval 1 (as indicated in<br />

Picture 2). In <strong>the</strong> same window one needs to specify <strong>the</strong> Verbal Description <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

simulation which is obligatory. Then we click Solve.<br />

Picture 2: Simulation process in RunGEM<br />

Source: The RunGEM programme by Monash University<br />

After that <strong>the</strong> window with Accuracy Summary showing up to which decimals most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

variables and data estimates are calibrated, and 10 is <strong>the</strong> highest note. The results appear in<br />

<strong>the</strong> next folder <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> RunGEM menu.<br />

20


6. In <strong>the</strong> RESULTS folder one can see how individual variables reacted to <strong>the</strong> shocks<br />

imposed. There is also a group <strong>of</strong> main variables at <strong>the</strong> national level to look at first, so<br />

called Macros. There one can see all <strong>the</strong> variables from <strong>the</strong> „back <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> envelop equations‟.<br />

This makes <strong>the</strong> interpretation easy, so that it can go from <strong>the</strong> broader picture <strong>of</strong> what<br />

happened to <strong>the</strong> economy down to <strong>the</strong> regional and sectoral analysis. All <strong>the</strong> variables in <strong>the</strong><br />

solution file are presented as a percentage changes compared to <strong>the</strong> base year, unless <strong>the</strong>y<br />

are written in capital letters – <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>y indicate changes in levels.<br />

6 Conclusions and summary<br />

In D3.2.2 and here we have added altoge<strong>the</strong>r six new features into <strong>the</strong> base <strong>model</strong>. They are: <strong>the</strong><br />

land factor, different real wage <strong>the</strong>ories, <strong>the</strong> Stone-Geary utility function (instead <strong>of</strong> Cobb-<br />

Douglas), public sector accounting, DPSV investment rule and BOT equations. Thanks to <strong>the</strong>se<br />

additions we have now three primary production factors: labour, capital, and land. Besides, now we<br />

can experiment with different wage <strong>the</strong>ories: sticky wages, adjusted Phillips curve or Wage curve<br />

based real wages. The Cobb-Douglas utility function has been replaced with <strong>the</strong> Stone-Geary<br />

leading to Linear Expenditure System, which is more sophisticated. Public sector accounting shows<br />

<strong>the</strong> tax revenues collected, and transfers given. The DPSV investment rule quarantees that<br />

investments within <strong>the</strong> same year are directed to those sectors that improve <strong>the</strong>ir relative<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>itability. <strong>Final</strong>ly, <strong>the</strong> BOT equations make it possible to account for <strong>the</strong> external EU c<strong>of</strong>inancing<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Pillar II measures from <strong>the</strong> EARDF budget.<br />

After introducing <strong>the</strong> latest two additions to <strong>the</strong> base <strong>model</strong>: <strong>the</strong> DPSV investment rule and <strong>the</strong><br />

BOT equations, it also provides a manual type <strong>of</strong> explanation on how to carry out simulations <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

impact that Rural Development Programs have on <strong>the</strong> regional economies (NUTS2) in EU27+. In<br />

particular it shows how to use RegCGEEU27+ <strong>model</strong> in <strong>the</strong> GEMPACK program in order to <strong>model</strong><br />

all rural development measures. The paper suggests <strong>the</strong> parametrization <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> shocks for identified<br />

groups <strong>of</strong> RD measures, <strong>the</strong>n it explains how to run <strong>the</strong> simulations.<br />

It is important to mention that <strong>the</strong>re is no one way to <strong>model</strong> RD measures and <strong>the</strong>re is no widely<br />

agreed consensus on how to do this. Therefore, <strong>the</strong> proposed simulations have a bit experimental<br />

character. However, <strong>the</strong>y are <strong>the</strong> best, as to <strong>the</strong> knowledge <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> authors, given <strong>the</strong> current <strong>model</strong><br />

structure <strong>of</strong> RegGCEEUE27+. At <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> day, <strong>the</strong> agricultural economists should decide<br />

about final parameterization, taking note <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> base <strong>model</strong>.<br />

The obvious challenge is to simulate such complex policy as <strong>the</strong> CAP (especially Pillar II) at <strong>the</strong><br />

regional level. That means that all shocks need to be implemented for c.a. 300 regions. It poses a<br />

challenge not only at <strong>the</strong> stage <strong>of</strong> implementation but also for interpretation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> results, where<br />

comparisons <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> effect will have to be made with reference to <strong>the</strong> difference in structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

funds obtained by each region within Pillar II.<br />

21


In order to grasp <strong>the</strong> reality <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> simulation we introduced an important feature that allows<br />

specifying to what extent <strong>the</strong> policy is financed from <strong>the</strong> national budgets vs. <strong>the</strong> total EU budget.<br />

This affect <strong>the</strong> simulation results and bring <strong>the</strong>m more to <strong>the</strong> reality.<br />

The example how to simulate <strong>the</strong> policy in RunGEM is not <strong>the</strong> only option. The simulations can be<br />

run also in WinGEM, but <strong>the</strong> reason <strong>the</strong> former was used is that it is precisely designed by CoPS,<br />

Monash University, for running simulations once <strong>the</strong> <strong>model</strong> is fixed. The simulation can be built in<br />

a step by step routine which is easy to follow. At <strong>the</strong> end some general hints are given for<br />

interpretation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> results, however only after true simulations <strong>the</strong>y can be fully explored.<br />

7 List <strong>of</strong> measures under 2007-2013 RDPs<br />

111 Vocational training and information actions<br />

112 Setting up <strong>of</strong> young farmers<br />

113 Early retirement<br />

114 Use <strong>of</strong> advisory services<br />

115 Setting up <strong>of</strong> management, relief and advisory services<br />

121 Modernisation <strong>of</strong> agricultural holdings<br />

122 Improvement <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economic value <strong>of</strong> forests<br />

123 Adding value to agricultural and forestry products<br />

124 Cooperation for development <strong>of</strong> new products<br />

125 Infrastructure related to agriculture and forestry<br />

126 Restoring agricultural production potential<br />

131 Meeting standards based on Community legislation<br />

132 Participation <strong>of</strong> farmers in food quality schemes<br />

133 Information and promotion activities for producer groups<br />

141 Semi-subsistence farming<br />

142 Producer groups<br />

143 Direct Payment (Bulgaria + Romania)<br />

211 Natural handicap payments to farmers (mountain areas)<br />

212 Payments to farmers in areas with handicaps (not mountain)<br />

213 Natura 2000 payments and linked to Directive 2000/60/EC<br />

214 Agri-environment payments<br />

215 Animal welfare payments<br />

216 Non-productive investments<br />

221 First afforestation <strong>of</strong> agricultural land<br />

222 First establishment <strong>of</strong> agr<strong>of</strong>orestry systems on agri. land<br />

223 First afforestation <strong>of</strong> non-agricultural land<br />

224 Natura 2000 payments<br />

225 Forest-environment payments<br />

226 Restoring forestry potential and introducing prevention ...<br />

227 Non-productive investments<br />

311 Diversification into non-agricultural activities<br />

312 Business creation and development<br />

22


313 Encouragement <strong>of</strong> tourism activities<br />

321 Basic services for <strong>the</strong> economy and rural population<br />

322 Village renewal and development<br />

323 Conservation and upgrading <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rural heritage<br />

331 Training and information<br />

341 Skills acquisition and animation for Local Development Strategies (LDS)<br />

411 Implementing LDS (competitiveness)<br />

412 Implementing LDS (environment/land)<br />

413 Implementing LDS (quality <strong>of</strong> life/diversification)<br />

421 Implementing cooperation projects<br />

431 Running <strong>the</strong> local action group, skills acquisition, animation<br />

511 Technical Assistance<br />

8 Bibliography<br />

Böhringer, C., T. F. Ru<strong>the</strong>rford i W. Wiegard (2007). Computable General Equilibrium Analysis<br />

Opening a Black Box. Discussion Paper, Nr 03-56. Mannheim, Centre for European Economic<br />

Research, ZEW.<br />

Borges, A. M. (1986). "Applied General Equilibrium Models: An Assessment <strong>of</strong> Their Usefulness<br />

for Policy Analysis." OECD Economic Studies 7: 7-43.<br />

Dixon, P. D. and Rimmer M. T. (2002) Dynamic General Equilibrium Modelling for Forecasting<br />

and Policy: A Practical Guide and Documentation <strong>of</strong> MONASH. North-Holland Amsterdam.<br />

Dixon, P. B., B. R. Parmenter, J. Sutton and D. P. Vincent (1982) ORANI: A Multisectoral Model<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Australian Economy. Amsterdam: North Holland.<br />

GEMPACK Documentation (2002) by Centre <strong>of</strong> Policy Studies and Impact Project, Monash<br />

University, Melbourne, Australia<br />

Giesecke, J. A. and Madden J. R. (2003) A large-scale dynamic multi-regional CGE <strong>model</strong> with an<br />

illustrative application, Review <strong>of</strong> Urban and Regional Development Studies 15, 2–25.<br />

Harrison W. J. and Pearson K. R. (2002) GEMPACK User Documentation. Centre for Policy<br />

Studies and Impact Project, Monash University, Melbourne Australia.<br />

Honkatukia, J. i R. Vaittinen (2003). POLGEM, A Computable General Equilibrium Model for<br />

Poland. Government Institute for Economic Research, Finland.<br />

Horridge, M. (2003) ORANI-G: A Generic Single-Country Computable General Equilibrium<br />

Model. Centre <strong>of</strong> Policy Studies, Monash University, http://www.monash.edu.au/<br />

23


policy/oranig.htm.<br />

Horridge, M. and G. Wittwer (2008) Creating and managing an impossibly large CGE database that<br />

is up-to-date. Centre <strong>of</strong> Policy Studies, Monash University, General Paper No. G-175.<br />

Partridge, M. D. and Rickman D. S. (1998) Regional computable general equilibrium <strong>model</strong>ling: a<br />

survey and critical appraisal, International Regional Science Review 21, 205–248.<br />

Peter, M. W., Horridge M., Meagher G. A., Naqvi F. and Parmenter B. R. (1996) The Theoretical<br />

Structure <strong>of</strong> MONASH-MRF . Preliminary Working Paper no. OP-85, IMPACT Project, Monash<br />

University, Clayton, April.<br />

Schwarm W. and Cutler H. (2003) Building small city and town SAMs and CGE <strong>model</strong>s, Review <strong>of</strong><br />

Urban and Regional Development Studies 15, 132–147.<br />

Törmä, H. (2008) Do small town development projects matter, and can CGE help? Spatial<br />

Economic Analysis, 3:2, 247–268.<br />

Törmä, H. and Reini K. (2009) Regional Economic Effects <strong>of</strong> Finnish Mining Sector on Business<br />

Structure and Employment. University <strong>of</strong> Helsinki, Ruralia Institute. Reports 37.<br />

Törmä, H. and Ru<strong>the</strong>rford T. F. (1993) Integrating Finnish Agriculture into EC‟s Common<br />

Agricultural Policy. Research Report No. 13. Government Institute for Economic Research<br />

Helsinki.<br />

Törmä, H. and Ru<strong>the</strong>rford T. F. (2002) Regional Economic Effects <strong>of</strong> Building and Using <strong>the</strong><br />

Tornio-Kemi Highway, Road Administration <strong>of</strong> Lappi, printed series (in Finnish, English version<br />

available from www.helsinki.fi/ruralia/research/regfin.htm). (accessed 1 November 2007)<br />

Törmä, H., Ru<strong>the</strong>rford T. F. and Vaittinen R. (1995) What will EU Membership and <strong>the</strong> Value<br />

Added Tax Reform do to Finnish Food Economy? A Computable General Equilibrium Analysis,<br />

Discussion Paper 88, Helsinki, Government Institute for Economic Research.<br />

Wittwer, G. and Horridge M. (2010) Bringing regional detail to a CGE <strong>model</strong> using census data,<br />

Spatial Economic Analysis, Volume 5 Issue 2, pp 229-255, Routledge [Jun 3, 2010].<br />

24

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!