27.01.2014 Views

Bundling, Tying, and Portfolio Effects: Part 1 Conceptual Issues

Bundling, Tying, and Portfolio Effects: Part 1 Conceptual Issues

Bundling, Tying, and Portfolio Effects: Part 1 Conceptual Issues

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

power in two goods. However, in this model, bundling by the incumbent is a profitable<br />

<strong>and</strong> hence credible response to entry. <strong>Bundling</strong> is desirable pre-entry due to price<br />

discrimination; bundling is profitable post-entry due to its effect of mitigating the cost of<br />

entry. A single-product firm will find it difficult to enter against a multi-product incumbent<br />

who can bundle. The underlying intuition is that in the presence of a bundle, an entrant<br />

will find its market limited to the few customers who like its one product <strong>and</strong> are not<br />

interested in the other products in the bundle. For example, to compete against<br />

Microsoft Office, an entrant with a superior word processing program might only be able<br />

to attack customers who care about word processing <strong>and</strong> not about presentation<br />

software or spreadsheets. We explore this model in detail in Section 4.4.2.<br />

3.3.4 EXCEPTION #4: CREATING EFFICIENCIES<br />

Our emphasis on leveraging market power has so far focused on strategic reasons to<br />

bundle. There are also efficiency reasons that create a strategic advantage when rivals<br />

cannot copy them.<br />

There are two ways in which bundling can create this type of advantage. One is through<br />

providing a superior product <strong>and</strong> the other is through providing more efficient pricing.<br />

In both of these cases, the bundled good market must not be competitive, as otherwise<br />

pricing would already be efficient, <strong>and</strong> rivals would be able to use the competitive supply<br />

to match any value-enhancing bundled offering.<br />

In the case of the pricing side, bundling can be used as a tool to eliminate double<br />

marginalisation. 31 As such, it allows a firm to undercut rivals who sell their product<br />

individually. Whether or not such a strategy applies to a particular market or not is a<br />

surprisingly subtle issue. There are many hidden assumption for this result to hold.<br />

We discuss these issues in much greater detail both in Sections 4.3.2.2 <strong>and</strong> 4.4.1<br />

<strong>and</strong> in connection with the GE-Honeywell merger case study in <strong>Part</strong> II, Section IV.<br />

A second way in which competitive advantage can arise is on the value side, where<br />

bundling can be used to increase the value of the firm’s offering relative to that of a rival.<br />

This is a topic that has not been addressed in the literature. The advantage arises when<br />

customers value variety, as might be the case at a ski resort. A firm gains an advantage<br />

when it puts together a variety bundle that allows the customer to choose among<br />

several options, as in a multi-mountain ski pass. When rivals cannot duplicate this<br />

strategy, the result is a sustained competitive advantage <strong>and</strong> possibly a dominant or<br />

leading market position. We discuss these issues first in Sections 4.4.4 <strong>and</strong> 5.3, <strong>and</strong><br />

again in regard to the Aspen Ski case in <strong>Part</strong> II, Section VII.<br />

We have provided an introduction to the primary antitrust issues surrounding bundling.<br />

We have shown that bundling (along with metering <strong>and</strong> tying) can be a profitable<br />

strategy. It is now appropriate to examine each of the motivations for bundling in detail.<br />

31 Double marginalisation is the extra inefficiency caused by the wholesaler marking up the manufacturer’s price when that manufacturer<br />

has market power <strong>and</strong> thus sets a price above marginal cost. For example, if a monopolist with zero marginal costs faced a linear<br />

market dem<strong>and</strong>, q = 1 - p, it would maximise profits at a price p=1/2. But if it had to sell through a wholesaler, it would optimally<br />

charge 1/2 to the wholesaler who would mark the price up again to 3/4. The mathematics of this example is worked out in Annex A,<br />

where we connect the traditional vertical double marginalisation to the Cournot double markup of complements.<br />

27

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!