07.03.2014 Views

Diversification and Horticultural Crops: A Case of Himachal Pradesh

Diversification and Horticultural Crops: A Case of Himachal Pradesh

Diversification and Horticultural Crops: A Case of Himachal Pradesh

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

DIVERSIFICATION AND<br />

HORTICULTURAL CROPS: A<br />

CASE OF HIMACHAL PRADESH<br />

THESIS SUBMITTED TO THE UNIVERSITY OF MYSORE<br />

THROUGH THE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS,<br />

UNIVERSITY OF MYSORE, MYSORE<br />

FOR THE DEGREE OF<br />

DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY IN ECONOMICS<br />

By:<br />

PRADEEP KUMAR MEHTA<br />

UNDER THE SUPERVISION OF<br />

DR M. MAHADEV A,<br />

ASSOCIATE PROFESSOR,<br />

ADRTC, ISEC, BANGALORE- 560078<br />

MAY 2009


DECLARATION<br />

I declare that this thesis titled "<strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong>: A <strong>Case</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>" is the result <strong>of</strong> my own work <strong>and</strong> that it has not been submitted<br />

previously, either wholly or in part, to this University or any other University for any<br />

Degree or Diploma. Due acknowledgements have been made wherever anything has been<br />

borrowed from other sources.<br />

r<br />

Date: tv~ \ ) -' 2 (l (1 ~<br />

adeep Kumar Mehta)<br />

Doctoral Fellow<br />

Agricultural Development <strong>and</strong> Rural Transformation Centre<br />

INSTITUTE FOR SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC CHANGE<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>. V.K.R.V. Rao Avenue, Nagarbhavi, Bangalore. 560072, India<br />

.0


CERTIFICATE<br />

I hereby certifY that the present thesis titled "<strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong>:<br />

A <strong>Case</strong> <strong>of</strong> Himacbal Pradesb" incorporates the result <strong>of</strong> the independent research <strong>of</strong><br />

Pradeep Kumar Mehta, Doctoral Fellow, Agricultural Development <strong>and</strong> Rural<br />

Transformation Centre, Institute for Social <strong>and</strong> Economic Change, Bangalore, conceived,<br />

designed <strong>and</strong> carried out under my guidance <strong>and</strong> supervision.<br />

I also certify that it has not previously formed the basis for the award <strong>of</strong> any Degree,<br />

Diploma or Associate Fellowship <strong>of</strong> the Mysore University or any other University.<br />

Date:<br />

~<br />

(M. Mabadeva)'<br />

Associate Pr<strong>of</strong>essor<br />

Agricultural Development <strong>and</strong> Rural Transformation Centre<br />

INSTITUTE FOR SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC CHANGE<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>. V.K.R.V. Rao Avenue, Nagarbhavi, Bangalore.560072, India


Dedicated to,<br />

My Dearest Father Late Shri. Ram Pal Mehta


ACKNOWLEDGEMENT<br />

PhD. is a long way to look back. In the process, one find many people, who have helped<br />

to come out <strong>of</strong> slack phases, dilemma, <strong>and</strong> confusion <strong>and</strong> have shown the right path. I<br />

owe greatly to Pr<strong>of</strong>. R.S. Deshp<strong>and</strong>e, who put me into research track <strong>and</strong> built the<br />

foundation <strong>of</strong> my Ph.D work. lowe to Dr. M. Mahadeva, more than my supervisor to<br />

guide me through out my research.<br />

There are many people who helped me out when I was struggling at different phases <strong>of</strong><br />

my PhD work. My special thanks to them, including Pr<strong>of</strong>. S. Bisalliah, Dr. Lalith Achoth,<br />

Dr. N. Jayaram, Dr. M.G Ch<strong>and</strong>rakant, Dr. Gopal Kadekodi, Dr. M.R. Narayana, Dr. S.<br />

Errapa, Pr<strong>of</strong>. S.Madeshwaran, Dr. Hemlata Rao, Dr. Ranvir Singh, Dr. P.K Joshi, Dr.<br />

Ramesh Ch<strong>and</strong>, Dr. V.S Vyas <strong>and</strong> Pr<strong>of</strong>. K.V. Raju.<br />

I thank all the government departments including, National <strong>Horticultural</strong> Board, New<br />

Delhi, Directorate <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, Horticulture, Economics <strong>and</strong> Statistics <strong>and</strong> L<strong>and</strong><br />

Records, Shimla, HP, who provided logistic <strong>and</strong> data support <strong>and</strong> helped me carrying out<br />

my fieldwork.<br />

This research could not have been carried out without the fellowship from ICSSR <strong>and</strong><br />

administrative support <strong>of</strong> ISEC, Bangalore. I, therefore, take this opportunity to thank<br />

ICSSR <strong>and</strong> ISEC administration, for providing me with the fellowship <strong>and</strong> necessary<br />

logistic support that enabled me to carry out this study. I sincerely acknowledge the help<br />

<strong>and</strong> assistance I received from Krishna Ch<strong>and</strong>ran, Satish Kamath <strong>and</strong> members <strong>of</strong> Library<br />

Staff, especially Kalyanappa, Venkatesh, <strong>and</strong> those from administration, especially<br />

Margaret, K S Narayana <strong>and</strong> Govinda Rao.<br />

Further, I express my gratitude to the Mysore University, Staff <strong>and</strong> Faculty for allowing<br />

me to register for Ph. 0 <strong>and</strong> for extending all possible support <strong>and</strong> cooperation in<br />

carrying out this study.<br />

However, I somewhere feci that to acknowledge is to deny, even if they are my own, like,<br />

my mother, brothers, wife, <strong>and</strong> sister-in-Iaws, Mrs. Deshp<strong>and</strong>e <strong>and</strong> Munna <strong>and</strong> friends<br />

like Khalil Shah, Yogeshwari, Prasana, Amalendu, Srikant, Prashob, Badri, Krushna,<br />

Sara la, Sashi, Mohan, An<strong>and</strong>a Vadivelu, .... <strong>and</strong> many more with whom I shared my joy<br />

<strong>and</strong> low times.<br />

PRADEEP KUMAR MEHTA


CONTENTS<br />

Declaration<br />

Certificate<br />

Acknowledgement<br />

Table <strong>of</strong> Contents<br />

List <strong>of</strong> Figures<br />

List <strong>of</strong> Tables<br />

Appendices<br />

List <strong>of</strong> Abbreviations<br />

Abstract<br />

III<br />

III<br />

V<br />

VI<br />

VII<br />

CHAPTER I<br />

INTRODUCTION<br />

1.1 Background<br />

1.2 Link Between Components <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Output Growth<br />

1.2.1 Diversity in the Cropping Pattern <strong>and</strong> Growth <strong>of</strong> Output<br />

1.2.2 L<strong>and</strong> Allocation in Favour <strong>of</strong> High Value <strong>Crops</strong> <strong>and</strong> Growth<br />

<strong>of</strong> Output<br />

1.2.3 Impact <strong>of</strong> Changing Cropping Pattern on Growth <strong>of</strong> Output<br />

1.3 Historical Context <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> its Need in Indian Agricultural<br />

Sector .<br />

1.4 <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> as a <strong>Case</strong> for <strong>Diversification</strong> in India<br />

1.5 Research Issues<br />

1.6 Research Questions<br />

I.7 Objectives <strong>of</strong> the Study_<br />

1.8 Sampling <strong>and</strong> Methodology<br />

1.9 Outline <strong>of</strong> the Study<br />

CHAPTER II<br />

REVIEW OF LITERATURE<br />

2.1 Factors Affcctin&.<strong>Diversification</strong>- Drivers <strong>and</strong> Constraints<br />

2.1.1 <strong>Diversification</strong> as a Changing Allocation <strong>of</strong> Area under <strong>Crops</strong><br />

2.1.2 <strong>Diversification</strong> in terms <strong>of</strong> Diversity in the Cropping Pattern<br />

2.1.3 <strong>Diversification</strong> represented as Share <strong>of</strong> High Value <strong>Crops</strong><br />

2.2 Risk, Uncertainty <strong>and</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> Decisi()lls<br />

2.3 Role <strong>of</strong> Changing Typology <strong>of</strong> Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> on Agricultural<br />

Growth<br />

CHAPTER III<br />

DIVERSIFICATION AND CROP OUTPUT GROWTH IN INDIA: A<br />

STATE LEVEL ANALYSIS<br />

3.1 Introduction<br />

3.2 Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> in India<br />

3.2. I Croppin.z Pattern Change in India<br />

1-31<br />

1<br />

6<br />

6<br />

7<br />

8<br />

9<br />

14<br />

16<br />

19<br />

20<br />

20<br />

26<br />

32-61<br />

33<br />

33<br />

40<br />

45<br />

49<br />

56<br />

62-93<br />

62<br />

64<br />

64


3.2.2 Diversity <strong>and</strong> Spread in the Cropping Pattern 66<br />

3.2.3 L<strong>and</strong> Allocation in Favour <strong>of</strong> High Value <strong>Crops</strong><br />

..._.<br />

69<br />

3.3 Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Income-Risk Pattern 70<br />

3.3.1 Trend in Income <strong>and</strong> Risk in Ag.riculture 70<br />

3.3.2 Link <strong>of</strong> Pattern <strong>of</strong>Cro!, <strong>Diversification</strong> with Income <strong>and</strong> Risk 72<br />

3.4 Relationship between Changing Cropping Pattern Mix <strong>and</strong> Growth <strong>of</strong> Crop 75<br />

Output<br />

3.4.1 Trends in Growth <strong>of</strong> Crop Output in States <strong>of</strong> India 75<br />

3.4.2 Model for Identification <strong>of</strong> Role <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> in Growth <strong>of</strong> 77<br />

Crop Output<br />

3.4.3 Components <strong>of</strong> Growth <strong>of</strong> CroP Output in India 80<br />

3.5 Summary 87<br />

CHAPTER IV<br />

DIVERSIFICATION AND HORTICULTURAL CROPS: A CASE OF 94-128<br />

HIMACHAL PRADESH<br />

4.1 Introduction 94<br />

4.2 <strong>Horticultural</strong> Sector in India 95<br />

4.2.1 State-Wise Pattern <strong>of</strong> Development <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> Sector 96<br />

4.3 <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong>: A <strong>Case</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> \01<br />

4.4 Significance <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> Cro!,s in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> \02<br />

4.5 An Overview <strong>of</strong> Selected Villages <strong>and</strong> Socio-Economic Characteristics <strong>of</strong> \08<br />

Fanners<br />

4.6 Income <strong>and</strong> Risk from <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> Production 1I2<br />

4.6.1 Income <strong>and</strong> Risk from Cauliflower 1I3<br />

4.6.2 Labour Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Output Supply Estimates: A Pr<strong>of</strong>it Function 1I8<br />

Approach<br />

4.6.3 Income <strong>and</strong> Risk from Apple 124<br />

6.7 Summary 127<br />

CHAPTER V<br />

ROLE OF ECONOMIC AND NON-ECONOMIC FACTORS IN 129-156<br />

DIVERSIFICATION FROM FOOD CROPS TO HORTICULTURAL<br />

CROPS<br />

5.1 Introduction 129<br />

5.2 Behaviour <strong>of</strong> Price <strong>and</strong> Area Cycles <strong>of</strong> Fruit <strong>and</strong> Vegetable crops 132<br />

5.3 <strong>Diversification</strong> from Food <strong>Crops</strong> towards <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> 138<br />

5.3.1 Food Security Concerns in <strong>Diversification</strong> 141<br />

5.3.2 Relative Significance <strong>of</strong> Economic <strong>and</strong> Non-Economic Factors in 144<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong><br />

5.4 Source <strong>of</strong> Diversity in Area Response to Cauliflower Prices 145<br />

5.5 Magnitude <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from Food <strong>Crops</strong> to <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> 150<br />

5.5.1 Socio Economic Features <strong>and</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> 150<br />

5.5.2 Factors Influencing Decision <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> towards 151<br />

<strong>Horticultural</strong> C,ops<br />

11


5.6 I Summary 154<br />

CHAPTER VI<br />

EXPECTATIONS, RISK ATTITUDE AND LAND ALLOCATION 157-187<br />

DECISIONS<br />

6.1 Introduction 157<br />

6.2 Price Expectations at Farm Level 160<br />

6.2.1 Dynamics <strong>of</strong> Price Expectations 160<br />

6.2.2 Relation <strong>of</strong> Price Expectation with Other Economic Factors 163<br />

6.3 Relative Role <strong>of</strong> Price <strong>and</strong> Yield Risk in Fruits <strong>and</strong> Vegetables 166<br />

6.4 Typology <strong>and</strong> Determinants <strong>of</strong> Risk Attitudes <strong>of</strong> Fanners 169<br />

6.5 Role <strong>of</strong> Economic Factors in L<strong>and</strong> allocation in Favour <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> 176<br />

<strong>Crops</strong><br />

6.5.1 Typology <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Allocation 176<br />

6.5.2 Socio Economic Characteristics <strong>and</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Allocation 177<br />

6.5.3 L<strong>and</strong> Allocation at Different Levels <strong>of</strong> Expectations <strong>and</strong> Risk 180<br />

Attitudes<br />

6.5.4 Determinants <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Allocation in Favour <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> 182<br />

6.6 Summary 184<br />

CHAPTER VII<br />

CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS 188-204<br />

REFERENCES AND SELECTED BIBLIOGRAPHY 205-220<br />

LIST OF FIGURES<br />

1.1 <strong>Diversification</strong> by Substitution <strong>and</strong> Expansion 4<br />

1.2 Map <strong>of</strong> Study Area 22<br />

1.3 Percentage <strong>of</strong> Gross Cropped Area under Fruits <strong>and</strong> Vegetables in Blocks <strong>of</strong> 24<br />

Shimla, 2006<br />

4.1 Compound Growth Rate in Area under <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> in India 97<br />

4.2 Location Quotient <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> in India 100<br />

4.3 Agro-Climatic Zones in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> 103<br />

4.4 Economics <strong>of</strong> Cauliflower Crop 115<br />

4.5 Economics <strong>of</strong> Cauliflower by Farm Size for Different Level <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> 115<br />

Allocation<br />

4.6 Sensitivity Analysis <strong>of</strong> Income from Cauliflower 117<br />

4.7 Sensitivity Analysis <strong>of</strong> Income from Cauliflower by Farm Size 117<br />

5.1 Types <strong>of</strong> Area <strong>and</strong> Price Cycles 133<br />

5.2 Trend in Area <strong>and</strong> Price <strong>of</strong> Apple in Shimla 137<br />

LIST OF TABLES<br />

1.1 Dem<strong>and</strong> for Various Foods in India- 2015 <strong>and</strong> 2030 16<br />

1.2 Compound Growth Rates in Area <strong>of</strong> Major Crop Groups m Blocks <strong>of</strong> 23<br />

111


Shimla, 1997-2006<br />

1.3 Absolute Change in Area under <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> in Blocks <strong>of</strong> Shimla, 24<br />

1997-2006<br />

1.4 <strong>Diversification</strong> Indexes <strong>of</strong> Blocks, 2006 25<br />

3.1 Contribution <strong>of</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> to Gross Cropped Area <strong>and</strong> Value <strong>of</strong> Output Produced 65<br />

in Agricultural Sector in India<br />

3.2 Number <strong>of</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> Produced by States in India 67<br />

3.3 Trends in Spread or Concentration in Cropping Pattern by Indian States 68<br />

3.4 Share <strong>of</strong> Non-Food <strong>Crops</strong> in Gross Cropped Area in India 70<br />

3.5 Ranking <strong>of</strong> States According to Gross Value <strong>of</strong> Output per ha @ 1993-94 71<br />

pnces<br />

3.6 Coefficient <strong>of</strong> Variation in Gross Value <strong>of</strong> Output @ 1993-94 prices 72<br />

3.7 Growth <strong>and</strong> Variability <strong>of</strong> Income According to Spread <strong>and</strong> Concentration <strong>of</strong> 74<br />

Cropping Pattern<br />

3.8 Growth <strong>and</strong> Variability <strong>of</strong> Income According to <strong>Diversification</strong> towards 75<br />

Non-Food <strong>Crops</strong><br />

3.9 Trend in the Growth Rates <strong>of</strong> Crop Output in States 77<br />

3.10 Contribution <strong>of</strong> Different Components in Growth <strong>of</strong> Gross Value <strong>of</strong> Output 81<br />

by Regions in India<br />

3.11 Area Expansion <strong>and</strong> Substitution Effect in India 85<br />

3.12 Factors Influencing Nature <strong>and</strong> Direction <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> in India 87<br />

4.1 Share <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> in the Total Value <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Output in 98<br />

India<br />

4.2 Net Returns from Various <strong>Crops</strong> in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>, 2001 104<br />

4.3 Productivity <strong>of</strong> Major <strong>Crops</strong> in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> <strong>and</strong> India, 2001 (Rs.lha) 104<br />

4.4 Growth Rate in Area <strong>and</strong> Value <strong>of</strong> Output <strong>of</strong> Major Crop Groups in HP 105<br />

4.5 Share <strong>of</strong> Crop Groups in Gross Value <strong>of</strong> Output in Agriculture in HP \05<br />

4.6 Compound Growth Rates in Area <strong>of</strong> Major <strong>Crops</strong> in Districts <strong>of</strong> HP 106<br />

4.7 Value <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Output <strong>and</strong> Productivity in Districts <strong>of</strong>HP \07<br />

4.8 Details <strong>of</strong> the Selected Villages 109<br />

4.9 Farm Size <strong>and</strong> Sampling from the Selected Villages 1\0<br />

4.10 Demographic Features <strong>of</strong> the Selected Farmers III<br />

4.11 Input Use Behaviour <strong>and</strong> Other Farm-related Characteristics <strong>of</strong> the Selected 112<br />

Farmers<br />

4.12 Farm Size <strong>and</strong> Resource Allocation by Cauliflower Growers 114<br />

4.13 Trend in Price <strong>and</strong> Yield <strong>of</strong> Cauliflower Crop 116<br />

4.14 Joint Estimation <strong>of</strong> Pr<strong>of</strong>it Function <strong>and</strong> Labour Dem<strong>and</strong> Function with 121<br />

Current Price<br />

4.15 Joint Estimation <strong>of</strong> Pr<strong>of</strong>it Function <strong>and</strong> Labour Dem<strong>and</strong> Function with 121<br />

Expected Price<br />

4.16 Indirect Estimates <strong>of</strong> Production Function Coefficients 122<br />

4.17 Labour Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Reduced Form Output Elasticities 123<br />

4.18 Farm Size <strong>and</strong> Resource Allocation by Apple Growers 125<br />

4.19 Economics <strong>of</strong> Apple Production by Farm Size 126<br />

IV


4.20 Simulation Analysis <strong>of</strong> Apple Production by Farm Size 127<br />

5.1 Area, Production <strong>and</strong> Yield <strong>of</strong> Cauliflower in Shimla, HP, 1998-2006 135<br />

5.2 Seasonal Price <strong>of</strong> Cauliflower in Shimla, HP, 2004-06 135<br />

5.3 Area, Production <strong>and</strong> Price <strong>of</strong> Apple in Shimla, HP, 1993-2002 137<br />

5.4 Typology <strong>and</strong> Extent <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> towards <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> 140<br />

5.5 Typology <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> towards <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> by Farm Size 141<br />

5.6 Cropping Pattern Shift <strong>and</strong> Food Self-Sufficiency among <strong>Horticultural</strong> Crop 143<br />

Growers<br />

5.7 Level <strong>of</strong> Subsistence among the <strong>Horticultural</strong> Crop Growers by Farm Size 143<br />

5.8 Relative Importance <strong>of</strong> Factors for <strong>Diversification</strong> towards <strong>Horticultural</strong> 145<br />

<strong>Crops</strong><br />

5.9 Average Values <strong>of</strong> Descriptive Variables among Cauliflower Growers 148<br />

5.10 Socio-Economic Characteristics at Different Levels <strong>of</strong> Shift in Cropping 151<br />

Pattern<br />

5.11 Factors Affecting Decision for <strong>Diversification</strong> towards <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> 153<br />

6.1 Farmers Experience with Price <strong>of</strong> Cauliflower <strong>and</strong> Apple (Rs./kg) 162<br />

6.2 Comparison <strong>of</strong> Actual Results <strong>and</strong> Farmers' Expected Values <strong>of</strong> Selected 163<br />

Distributions<br />

6.3 Input Use Propensities <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> Crop Growers According to Different 164<br />

Price Expectations<br />

6.4 Factors Explaining Price Expectations <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> Crop Growers 166<br />

6.5 Decomposition <strong>of</strong> Income Risk from Apple <strong>and</strong> Cauliflower 168<br />

6.6 Correlation between Production <strong>and</strong> Price <strong>of</strong> Apple <strong>and</strong> Cauliflower, 2004- 169<br />

06<br />

6.7 Frequency Distribution <strong>of</strong> Farmers on the Basis <strong>of</strong> Risk Attitudes 173<br />

6.8 Factors Influencing Risk Attitudes <strong>of</strong> Farmers 175<br />

6.9 Extent <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> allocation in Favour <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> 177<br />

6.10 Extent <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Allocation in Favour <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> by Farm Size 177<br />

6.11 Socio-Economic Characteristics at Different Levels <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Allocation 178<br />

6.12 Income-Consumption Gap at Different Levels <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Allocation 179<br />

6.13 Role <strong>of</strong> Expectations <strong>and</strong> Risk on Extent <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Allocation in Favour <strong>of</strong> 181<br />

<strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong><br />

6.14 Factors Affecting L<strong>and</strong> Allocation Decisions <strong>of</strong> Farmers Producing 184<br />

<strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong><br />

APPENDICES<br />

Al.1<br />

Al.2<br />

A3.1<br />

A3.2<br />

A 3.3<br />

A 3.4<br />

Facets <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

Indicators <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

List <strong>of</strong> <strong>Crops</strong><br />

Share <strong>of</strong> Rice <strong>and</strong> Wheat in Gross Cropped Area in India<br />

Compound Growth Rates <strong>of</strong> Area under Rice<br />

Compound Growth Rates <strong>of</strong> Area under Wheat<br />

28<br />

29<br />

90<br />

90<br />

91<br />

91<br />

v


A3.5<br />

A3.6<br />

A3.7<br />

Compound Growth Rates <strong>of</strong> Area under Non-Food <strong>Crops</strong> 92<br />

Gross Value <strong>of</strong> Output <strong>of</strong> States in India @ 1993-94 prices 92<br />

Distribution <strong>of</strong> States by Trend towards Spread or Concentration in Cropping 93<br />

Pattern<br />

A 3.8 Distribution <strong>of</strong> States by Trend in Shift <strong>of</strong> Cropping Pattern towards Non- 93<br />

Food <strong>Crops</strong><br />

A 6.1<br />

A 6.2<br />

Fanners Experience with Price <strong>of</strong> Cauliflower (Rs./kg) 187<br />

Fanners Experience with Price <strong>of</strong> Apple (Rs./kg) 187<br />

LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS<br />

ANOVA: Analysis <strong>of</strong> Variance<br />

CPI-AL: Consumer Price Index- Agricultural Labourer<br />

CV: Coefficient <strong>of</strong> Variation<br />

DARA: Decreasing Absolute Risk Aversion<br />

EU: Expected Utility<br />

F&V: Fruits <strong>and</strong> Vegetables<br />

GCA: Gross Cropped Area<br />

HP: <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong><br />

HVCs: High Value <strong>Crops</strong><br />

HYV: High Yielding Varieties<br />

IRR: Internal Rate <strong>of</strong> RetUrit<br />

J&K: Jammu & Kashmir<br />

L&S: Lahaul & Spiti<br />

MCN: Minimum Consumption Needs<br />

MT : Metric Tones<br />

NHB: National <strong>Horticultural</strong> Board<br />

NPV: Net Present Value<br />

OFI: Off-farm Income<br />

RC: Risk Coefficient<br />

SUR: Seemingly Unrelated Regression<br />

TE: Triennium Ending<br />

TMO: Technology Mission on Oilseeds<br />

TVP: Total Value Productivity<br />

UOP: Unit Output Price<br />

VaR: Value at Risk<br />

wrO: World Trade Organization<br />

VI


ABSTRACT<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> is one <strong>of</strong> the components <strong>of</strong> growth in addition to area expansion <strong>and</strong><br />

technology development. Recently, diversification assumed high importance in the recent<br />

past due to two reasons; fatigue in other components <strong>of</strong> growth in Indian agriculture <strong>and</strong><br />

new opportunities for diversification towards high value crops due to both the dem<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> supply side factors. In this context, we investigate the relative role <strong>of</strong> diversification<br />

on output growth, <strong>and</strong> growth inducive or depressive impact <strong>of</strong> changing process <strong>of</strong> crop<br />

diversification in India. Studies dealing with diversification mainly concentrated on price<br />

<strong>of</strong> the crop <strong>and</strong> considered price as one <strong>of</strong> the major guiding factors in the decisionmaking.<br />

However, price may not be the only factor in decision-making; heterogeneity in<br />

resource <strong>and</strong> capital endowments <strong>of</strong> farmers <strong>and</strong> difference in their access to input <strong>and</strong><br />

output markets also playa role in decision-making. It could be hypothesized that farmers<br />

with relatively higher level <strong>of</strong> productivity may diversify more with lower price<br />

expectations. Thus, we analysed the nature <strong>of</strong> price expectations <strong>of</strong> the diversified<br />

farmers, examine its relationship with other economic factors <strong>and</strong> identify the role <strong>of</strong><br />

different expectations <strong>of</strong> price, yield <strong>and</strong> income <strong>of</strong> farmers on their diversification<br />

decisions. <strong>Horticultural</strong> crops are also considered as risky crops due to high fluctuations<br />

in the price <strong>and</strong> production, thus, finally, we estimated the role <strong>of</strong> overall risk <strong>of</strong><br />

production <strong>and</strong> consumption on the extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> horticultural<br />

crops?<br />

Undoubtedly, at the macro or state level, diversification has become a major<br />

component for stepping up growth. The picture <strong>of</strong> the last few decades points that the<br />

gain from diversification is contingent upon the technology development <strong>of</strong> high value<br />

crops in India. Within the horticultural sector, there are two different categories <strong>of</strong> crops<br />

i.e fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables <strong>and</strong> thus there is a need for different policies for these categories.<br />

Irrigation is vital for diversification towards vegetable crops, whereas availability <strong>of</strong><br />

labour is crucial for fruit crops. Development <strong>and</strong> integration <strong>of</strong> markets are vital to<br />

increase farmer's welfare; high price expectations are positively linked with the prices<br />

received by farmers over a period <strong>of</strong> time <strong>and</strong> this, in tum, influence their input use<br />

hehaviour <strong>and</strong> productivity. While, taking diversification decisions, farmers attach more<br />

Vll


importance to expected total net income from the crop <strong>and</strong> hence consider both the price<br />

<strong>and</strong> yield. Relative incomes from the crops explain the crop substitution decisions <strong>of</strong><br />

farmers i.e., farmers calculate the aggregate gain from the crop than considering only the<br />

price <strong>of</strong> the crop. The capacity to generate higher productivity <strong>and</strong> availability <strong>of</strong> better<br />

marketing prospects together explains farmers' decision. Thus, intervention in production<br />

technology <strong>and</strong> streamlining markets are concomitantly required; harping on market<br />

improvement for increasing l<strong>and</strong> in favour <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops will not suffice. In terms<br />

<strong>of</strong> risk, farmers are concerned not only about crop-specific risk but also their aggregate<br />

production <strong>and</strong> consumption risk. So improving farmers' orientation towards high value<br />

crops require intervention in food grain markets by improving the technology. Better<br />

technology in food crop can lead to increase in the productivity <strong>of</strong> food crops which<br />

would help in reducing consumption constraints for higher allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> to high<br />

value horticultural crops. In addition, development <strong>of</strong> labour market can be critical for<br />

l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions by farmers as it would help farmers to earn more income <strong>and</strong><br />

alleviate income constraints for diversification.<br />

Vlll


CHAPTER I<br />

INTRODUCTION<br />

1.1 Background<br />

The decision <strong>of</strong> diversification by a farmer is considered to be one <strong>of</strong> the major<br />

economic decisions that has strong bearing on his welfare in terms <strong>of</strong> income level <strong>and</strong><br />

variability in returns (Heady, 1952, Johnson <strong>and</strong> Brester, 2001, Pope <strong>and</strong> Prescott, 1980).<br />

In general, regular high income with less variability is considered welfare augmenting.<br />

Underst<strong>and</strong>ing the decision-making process <strong>of</strong> farmers in the context <strong>of</strong> poor growth<br />

either due to low income or high variability <strong>of</strong> returns is important especially, when the<br />

policy seeks to underst<strong>and</strong> the factors affecting shifting to high value crops like<br />

horticultural crops, in the event <strong>of</strong> stagnant yields <strong>of</strong> food-grains, poor agricultural<br />

growth <strong>and</strong> increased concern <strong>of</strong> farmers' welfare in terms <strong>of</strong> low <strong>and</strong> variable income<br />

(Joshi, 2005, Ch<strong>and</strong>, 2006, Evenson et al. 1999).<br />

In farm planning, farmer as a decision maker takes three decisions - what to<br />

produce, how to produce <strong>and</strong> how much to produce (Van <strong>and</strong> Keller, 2006). The farmer<br />

has to decide between alternative uses <strong>of</strong> resources at hislher disposal in order to address<br />

these three different but inter-related questions. While deliberating on these aspects, a<br />

farmer has to choose which crops to produce <strong>and</strong> to what extent to specialize, or<br />

alternatively diversify the area. This directly or indirectly affects the aggregate output at<br />

the farm. In general, there are three major components <strong>of</strong> aggregate output - area, crop<br />

yields <strong>and</strong> level <strong>of</strong> diversification. The growth <strong>of</strong> output could be improved by increasing<br />

the area under cultivation, either by extension or intensification <strong>of</strong> area or reducing the<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> production, either by decreasing the prices <strong>of</strong> inputs or cost <strong>of</strong> obtaining inputs, by<br />

introducing new technology that improves productivity <strong>of</strong> crops. In addition to these<br />

components or policy options, diversification is another major component <strong>of</strong> growth that<br />

influences output through its impact on cost, income <strong>and</strong> risk (Grimes, 1929).


Crop diversification is one <strong>of</strong> the sub-sets <strong>of</strong> a larger matrix <strong>of</strong> production<br />

alternatives in the cropping sector. From an economic point <strong>of</strong> view, diversification is<br />

treated from two analytical perspectives: as a problem <strong>of</strong> determining, given prices, the<br />

optimal crop mix on a production possibility frontier; <strong>and</strong> second as a mechanism for<br />

incorporating risk aversion into a fanner's decision making process in which crop<br />

specialisation may lead to highly unstable income due to variance in yield, production, or<br />

price for the particular crop (World Bank, 1988). In a broad manner, diversification is<br />

seen as having two main properties; it exp<strong>and</strong>s the production possibility set or area<br />

allocation frontier, thereby increasing opportunities for income generation <strong>and</strong><br />

employment creation. It also reduces the risk <strong>of</strong> having all <strong>of</strong> one's eggs in a basket with<br />

a few crops with potentially high covariance risk (Samuelson, 1967).<br />

There are several sub-components <strong>of</strong> diversification that include both the spatial<br />

<strong>and</strong> temporal aspects. There is a continuum <strong>of</strong> the decision making process in<br />

diversification, whereby farmers need to take four critical decisions that together, <strong>and</strong> not<br />

in isolation, affect their welfare in terms <strong>of</strong> income <strong>and</strong> risk outcomes. Farmers make<br />

choices in the context <strong>of</strong> their production possibility frontier, their expectations <strong>of</strong><br />

relative prices <strong>and</strong> their sense <strong>of</strong> risk from both an agronomic <strong>and</strong> market perspective for<br />

various alternatives (World Bank, 1990). The first decision is about the choice <strong>of</strong> number<br />

<strong>of</strong> crops. Within the area allocation or on the production possibility frontier, a farmer<br />

decides about the number <strong>of</strong> crops that could be produced. Some farmers prefer to<br />

produce more number <strong>of</strong> crops than others within a homogenous climatic <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong><br />

quality. This system <strong>of</strong> diversification is related purely to the diversity aspect, where<br />

diversification is only related to the number <strong>of</strong> crops produced.<br />

When a fanner decides about the number <strong>of</strong> crops, it influences the aggregate level<br />

<strong>of</strong> spread or concentration in the cropping pattern; this determines the ex tent <strong>of</strong><br />

specialisation at the farm level. In this context, diversification is seen not only in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

the number <strong>of</strong> crops but also in terms <strong>of</strong> the balance among different crops. The concept<br />

can be explained by considering minimum diversification as the practice <strong>of</strong> having a<br />

single crop <strong>and</strong> maximum diversification as equal distribution <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> to all crops<br />

(Grosskopf, et al. 1992). In previous cases, it could be seen that a household producing<br />

2


two crops would be considered more diversified than a household producing a single<br />

crop. But in the latter case, a household producing two crops, each contributing equally to<br />

the total, would be more diversified than a household with two crops, <strong>of</strong> which one crop<br />

covers 90 percent <strong>of</strong> the total area under cultivation (Minot et aI., 2006). Here, higher<br />

spread is synonymous to higher level <strong>of</strong> diversification. Higher spread in cropping pattern<br />

is expected to help farmers for in a fuller or better utilization <strong>of</strong> resources, in realizing<br />

regular <strong>and</strong> quick results <strong>and</strong> reducing risks out <strong>of</strong> crop or market failures.<br />

While taking decision on number <strong>of</strong> crops <strong>and</strong> level <strong>of</strong> spread in the cropping<br />

pattern, farmers also take another critical decision as to which crops to produce <strong>and</strong> how<br />

much l<strong>and</strong> to be allocated to each crop. There can be different combinations <strong>of</strong> low<br />

versus high value crops or mix <strong>of</strong> subsistence <strong>and</strong> commercial crops. The value <strong>of</strong> crops<br />

is determined on the basis <strong>of</strong> their capacity to generate economic returns per unit <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong><br />

or labour (Minot et aI., 2006). It is important to note that diversification from staple crop<br />

production into high-value crops need not imply greater diversity in crops. For example,<br />

if a mixed grain <strong>and</strong> cotton grower decides to specialize in cotton production, this would<br />

represent diversification into a high-value crop, but not diversification in the sense <strong>of</strong><br />

multiple cropping. Here, diversification is seen also from the angle <strong>of</strong> commercialization.<br />

Three components pertaining to spatial dimension <strong>of</strong> diversification as discussed<br />

above could be classified as:<br />

I. Diversity in the cropping pattern<br />

2. Spread <strong>of</strong> the cropping pattern<br />

3. L<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> high value crops<br />

Pingali <strong>and</strong> Rosegrant (1995) have viewed all these components <strong>of</strong> diversification<br />

in terms <strong>of</strong> three stages - subsistence, semi-commercial <strong>and</strong> commercial. According to<br />

them, in the first stage, when farming is characterized by higher level <strong>of</strong> subsistence, the<br />

level <strong>of</strong> diversity tends to be higher. As there is an increased tendency towards higher<br />

extent <strong>of</strong> commercialization or higher allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> in favour <strong>of</strong> high value crops,<br />

,uch farming may lead to high concentration. It conjectures a positive relation between<br />

3


levels <strong>of</strong> commercialization <strong>and</strong> increasing level <strong>of</strong> concentration at the farm level. It<br />

includes the process <strong>of</strong> switching from low value crops to high value crops.<br />

in addition to the spatial picture <strong>of</strong> diversification, there is also a temporal<br />

dimension. Over a period <strong>of</strong> time, due to changing market <strong>and</strong> technological conditions,<br />

etc., the cropping pattern undergoes change <strong>and</strong> thus alters the pattern <strong>of</strong> diversification.<br />

It also influences the extent <strong>of</strong> diversity, level <strong>of</strong> spread in cropping pattern <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong><br />

allocation across low <strong>and</strong> high value crops. TItis is especially because change in cropping<br />

pattern can take place either by substitution <strong>of</strong> crops, extensification <strong>of</strong> area or<br />

intensification <strong>of</strong> area. The difference in the pattern followed for crop shift results in<br />

difference in the spatial dimensions <strong>of</strong> diversification, which could be as shown in figure<br />

1.1:<br />

Figure 1.1: <strong>Diversification</strong> by Substitution <strong>and</strong> Expansion<br />

Crop A<br />

CropB<br />

A. Substitution B. Expansion or intensification<br />

Figure 1.1 depicts two distinct ways in which farmer may add area under any<br />

particular crop. When a farmer needs to increase the area under crop B, it can be done<br />

either by reducing the same extent <strong>of</strong> area under crop A or by increasing! adding area<br />

under cultivation, while keeping the area under crop A constant. An increase in area <strong>of</strong> a<br />

particular crop (crop B) by reducing the same amount <strong>of</strong> area <strong>of</strong> other crop (crop A)<br />

leaves the level <strong>of</strong> diversity unchanged. However, it may change the crop mix pattern due<br />

to cifferences in the values <strong>of</strong> the crops that alters the allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> among low <strong>and</strong><br />

high value crops. For the purpose <strong>of</strong> producing more crops or adding new crops to the<br />

prevailing crops, if farmer purchases new l<strong>and</strong> or else exp<strong>and</strong>s the production to the<br />

4


marginal l<strong>and</strong> previously uncultivated (adding area under cultivation) than substituting<br />

the crops, it would increase the level <strong>of</strong> diversity at the farm level. In such cases, the<br />

farmer may not require to forgo the prevailing cropping pattern; it leads only to increase<br />

in the level <strong>of</strong> diversity <strong>and</strong> spread in the cropping pattern.<br />

Increasing the total number <strong>of</strong> crops or having more diversity III the cropping<br />

pattern may not by itself ensure more income or less risk or both (Heady, 1952). This is<br />

also conditioned upon other typologies <strong>of</strong> diversification. All these typologies or<br />

components <strong>of</strong> diversification are inter-linked <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong>ten one typology <strong>of</strong> diversification<br />

precludes another typology <strong>of</strong> diversification '. The mutual exclusiveness or trade-<strong>of</strong>f can<br />

take place in several ways. As noted, there is a possibility that an increase in the<br />

allocation <strong>of</strong> area to high value crops in the portfolio could lead to a decline in the<br />

diversity <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern. It would represent diversification into high-value crops, but<br />

not diversification in the sense <strong>of</strong> multiple cropping. Hence one needs to be cautious in<br />

the distinction between "diversification into" <strong>and</strong> "diversification in". Also, much caution<br />

is needed in defining diversification on the basis <strong>of</strong> area <strong>and</strong> value. If a farmer grows peas<br />

in 2 hectare <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> rice in 10 hectare, with each crop yielding Rs. 1000 net income,<br />

then clearly, acreage proportions may be a deficient measure <strong>of</strong> diversification. For<br />

example, a farmer who grows peas in 6 hectare <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> rice in 6 hectare, with income<br />

on peas at Rs. 1000 <strong>and</strong> rice at Rs. 500. In this case, income proportions may be a poor<br />

measure <strong>of</strong> diversification (Pope <strong>and</strong> Prescott, 1980). Additionally, a conflict in<br />

diversification at macro <strong>and</strong> micro levels is possible. The extent <strong>of</strong> diversification at the<br />

macro (state or district) level does not always leads to same level <strong>of</strong> diversification at<br />

micro (farm) level. In the scenario <strong>of</strong> heterogeneous climatic zones, possibility exists that<br />

diversity <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern at macro level would result in a higher level <strong>of</strong><br />

specialisation at the micro level. There is also a distinction between diversification<br />

defined in a temporal <strong>and</strong> spatial manner. In the fonner case, it is about cropping pattern<br />

shift <strong>and</strong> in the latter case it is about number <strong>of</strong> crops, spread in the cropping pattern <strong>and</strong><br />

l<strong>and</strong> allocation across low <strong>and</strong> high value crops. In addition, each component <strong>of</strong><br />

divcrsi fication influences growth in a different way.<br />

I The detailed infonnation about facets <strong>and</strong> indicators <strong>of</strong> diversification are provided in appendix 1.1 <strong>and</strong><br />

1.2<br />

5


1.2 Link between Components <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Output<br />

Growth<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> is one among the several components <strong>of</strong> growth, in addition to<br />

area under cultivation <strong>and</strong> crop productivity. As there are several sub-components <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification, there is a need to identify ways in which these sub-components influence<br />

growth <strong>of</strong> output.<br />

1.2.1 Diversity in the Cropping Pattern <strong>and</strong> Growth <strong>of</strong> Output<br />

Diversity or spread <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern influences the growth <strong>of</strong> output through its<br />

impact on both income <strong>and</strong> risk in one <strong>of</strong> the following ways: (i) by increasing the<br />

production <strong>of</strong> those crops that are relatively high in price <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong>fer satisfactory margins<br />

above the cost <strong>of</strong> production, (ii) by reducing the cost <strong>of</strong> producing all crops by<br />

distributing fixed costs over the larger number <strong>of</strong> crops without materially increasing<br />

variable costs <strong>and</strong> (iii) by securing more <strong>of</strong> the subsistence <strong>of</strong> the farmer <strong>and</strong> his family<br />

from the farm by producing for home use such products that are not <strong>of</strong> major importance<br />

in the agriculture <strong>of</strong> the region but can be satisfactorily produced in limited quantities<br />

(Grimes, 1929). Also, diversifying cropping pattern is one <strong>of</strong> the measures that farmers<br />

can take to cope with an uncertain future situation. There are two aspects <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification which deal with maximizing pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>and</strong> minimizing variance <strong>of</strong> returns.<br />

The first one is about planning diversification under perfect knowledge, as in the case <strong>of</strong><br />

individual farmer, wishing to maximize pr<strong>of</strong>its, will equalize the marginal rate <strong>of</strong> crop<br />

substitution with the price ratio <strong>of</strong> the crops. The task before the farmer is that <strong>of</strong><br />

maximising pr<strong>of</strong>it or optimize income. The other aspect <strong>of</strong> diversification is that <strong>of</strong><br />

minimising the variance <strong>of</strong> returns, i.e., putting a floor under the income level or<br />

preventing the occurrence <strong>of</strong> undesirable outcomes. The farmer, naturally, unable to<br />

predict price <strong>and</strong> yield outcomes, may wish to select a combination <strong>of</strong> crops or exhibit<br />

higher level <strong>of</strong> diversity in the cropping pattern which gives a steady year to year flow <strong>of</strong><br />

in,;ol1\e (Heady, 1952). But, the impact <strong>of</strong> diversity in the cropping pattern on risk is<br />

6


conditioned by the levels <strong>of</strong> correlation (positive, negative <strong>and</strong> zero) between the price<br />

<strong>and</strong> yields <strong>of</strong> the crops {lroduced (Quiroz <strong>and</strong> Valdes, 1995).<br />

1.2.2 L<strong>and</strong> Allocation in Favour <strong>of</strong> High Value <strong>Crops</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

Growth <strong>of</strong> Output<br />

L<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> high value crops is closely linked to output growth<br />

through its impact on l<strong>and</strong> productivity. L<strong>and</strong> productivity represents the average value <strong>of</strong><br />

output per acre <strong>and</strong> is not quite synonymous with per acre crop yield rates. Changes in<br />

l<strong>and</strong> productivity can be decomposed into three elements, i.e., change in yield <strong>of</strong> the<br />

crops produced, change in the cropping pattern <strong>and</strong> locational shift <strong>of</strong> crops. There are<br />

possibilities when l<strong>and</strong> productivity declines despite an increase in the yield rates <strong>of</strong> all<br />

crops, if the cropping pattern shifts from high yield crops to low yield crops. Shifting the<br />

location <strong>of</strong> the crops from one state or region to another also influences l<strong>and</strong> productivity<br />

in the absence <strong>of</strong> any change in the yield <strong>of</strong> all crops. If there is a relative shift in area<br />

under the i lb crop from states where its per hectare yield is lower to states where it is<br />

higher, it would impart a rising trend to its overall yield even if the per hectare yield in<br />

the individual states remained unchanged over time. Similarly, a shift in the total cropped<br />

area away from the crops with lower value <strong>of</strong> output per hectare towards crops with<br />

higher value <strong>of</strong> output per hectare would produce a rising trend in the index <strong>of</strong><br />

productivity, even if the yield <strong>of</strong> the individual crops remained unchanged over time.<br />

Thus, the growth <strong>of</strong> productivity is made up <strong>of</strong> three components respectively, reflecting<br />

the contribution <strong>of</strong>; a. cropping pattern changes, b. locational shifts <strong>of</strong> area under<br />

individual crops, <strong>and</strong> c. pure increase in the yields <strong>of</strong> individual crops in different regions<br />

(Narain, 1976). It is important to note that changes in cropping pattern from low value to<br />

high value crops <strong>and</strong> Iocational shift <strong>of</strong> crops from low productivity to high productivity<br />

regions always result in increase in income other things remaining constant.<br />

7


1.2.3 Impact <strong>of</strong> Changing Cropping Pattern on Growth <strong>of</strong><br />

Output<br />

Change in cropping pattern <strong>and</strong> resulting change in typologies <strong>of</strong> diversification can<br />

have either income inducing or depressing effects, which is not necessarily always linked<br />

positively with growth. Over-time, farmers or regions reallocate their l<strong>and</strong> among<br />

alternative crops that have different values. Since, the relative values <strong>of</strong> crops do not<br />

remain same, the changes in the crop mix vis a vis the values <strong>of</strong> different crops affect the<br />

income or output <strong>of</strong> farmers. The change in cropping pattern adversely affects income<br />

when farmers increase acreage under a particular crop whose relative yield or value as<br />

compared to other crops declines over a period <strong>of</strong> time. This is likely in the case <strong>of</strong><br />

several food crops. The objective <strong>of</strong> ensuring food security <strong>of</strong> the family may motivate<br />

the farmers to take such decisions. Also, additional factors like access to market <strong>and</strong><br />

resource availability influence these decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers. Increase in the relative weight<br />

<strong>of</strong> the crops in the gross cropped area, whose yield or value decline is indicative <strong>of</strong><br />

income-depressive effect <strong>of</strong> change in cropping pattern. It denotes that the crop structure<br />

has shifted in favour <strong>of</strong> those crops which have lower or poor growth <strong>of</strong> yield or value.<br />

The effects <strong>of</strong> change in cropping pattern become positive on growth <strong>of</strong> output, when the<br />

crop structure shifts in favour <strong>of</strong> those crops which exhibit higher growth <strong>of</strong> yield <strong>and</strong><br />

value. This denotes income-inducive effect <strong>of</strong> change in cropping pattern. In sum, the<br />

diversification strategy by the farmers can affect their income in either direction- positive<br />

or negative.<br />

The differences in dimensions <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>and</strong> its relationship with growth<br />

raise some important questions: first, why do farmers need diversification <strong>and</strong> under what<br />

context? <strong>Diversification</strong> has been a common phenomenon <strong>and</strong> Indian agriculture <strong>and</strong><br />

farmers in India are no exceptions. Secondly, as there could be either growth inducing or<br />

depressing effects <strong>of</strong> diversification, under which circumstances diversification assume<br />

imROrtance? Which is better process <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>and</strong> in which direction it must<br />

move? What are the areas <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>and</strong> finally, diversification at what level?<br />

These are discussed in the ensuing sections <strong>of</strong> this chapter.<br />

8


1.3 Historical Context <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> its Need in Indian<br />

Agricultural Sector<br />

After independence, Indian economy was confronting with the problem <strong>of</strong> food<br />

insecurity. Both the market <strong>and</strong> technology were under developed <strong>and</strong> these were<br />

responsible for low income <strong>and</strong> higher variability in the returns <strong>of</strong> food <strong>and</strong> non-food<br />

crops (Rudra, 1982). At that time, diversification was looked primarily from the angle <strong>of</strong><br />

risk <strong>and</strong> food security. <strong>Diversification</strong>, in terms <strong>of</strong> diversity <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern, was one<br />

<strong>of</strong> the means to minimise risk <strong>and</strong> overcome food insecurity. It was primarily the stateled<br />

diversification, where state sought to propagate diversification primarily to meet the<br />

food-security goals <strong>of</strong> the economy. The introduction <strong>of</strong> Green Revolution was one <strong>of</strong> the<br />

steps towards changing the orientation <strong>of</strong> Indian farmers towards adoption <strong>of</strong> new<br />

technology. This technology was limited to the introduction <strong>of</strong> High Yielding Varieties<br />

(HYV) <strong>of</strong> selected crops. It was expected to help farmers in terms <strong>of</strong> higher income or<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>and</strong> less variability <strong>of</strong> returns. Undoubtedly, this process led to many<br />

benefits, particularly in improving the growth <strong>of</strong> agricultural sector (Hazra, 2(03). The<br />

Technology Mission on Oilseeds (TMO) in late 19808 was an additional effort to<br />

improve technology in another vital sector <strong>of</strong> agriculture in India. Both <strong>of</strong> these efforts<br />

laid emphasize on technology. But, mechanism <strong>of</strong> price support <strong>and</strong> subsidies were<br />

operationaiized to improve such technology-led diversifICation. This type <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification could also be termed as resource-led, as resources like irrigation, <strong>and</strong> other<br />

inputs including high Yielding Varieties (HYVs) <strong>and</strong> fertilizer were provided to farmers<br />

<strong>and</strong> regions to push diversification. This process resulted in reduction in the level <strong>of</strong><br />

diversity among crops <strong>and</strong> instead increased concentration in cropping pattern in many<br />

states as large acreage was diverted towards few prominent crops like, rice <strong>and</strong> wheat.<br />

This development initiative or policy came critical lens, particularly after the emergence<br />

<strong>of</strong> World Trade Organization (WTO) in 1995 (Ch<strong>and</strong>, 2004). Liberalization <strong>of</strong><br />

agricultural sector <strong>and</strong> emphasis on international trade with reduction in support <strong>and</strong><br />

subsidies was the major agenda <strong>of</strong> this policy. At the same time, there were<br />

apprehensions that the impact <strong>of</strong> Green Revolution was fading away (Joshi et a!. 2(06). It<br />

was felt that in order to increase the growth <strong>of</strong> agricultural sector, it was critical to divert<br />

9


attention to other components <strong>of</strong> growth. This favoured the price or market-led<br />

diversification, where diversification is provoked by shifts in the sentiments <strong>of</strong> the market<br />

which is reflected in the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> the crops.<br />

Higher economic growth <strong>and</strong> increased per capita income during 1990s favoured<br />

the process <strong>of</strong> price-led diversification as it was based on shifting <strong>of</strong> area towards crops<br />

whose dem'lmd <strong>and</strong> consequently price, was increasing at a faster rate. In other words,<br />

after 1990, liberalization <strong>of</strong> the economy has created an opportunity by increasing the<br />

benefits from changing cropping pattern towards high value crops including non-food<br />

crops. High economic growth, rising per capita income <strong>and</strong> growing urbanization after<br />

1990 have been causing a shift in the consumption patterns towards high value crops like<br />

fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables <strong>and</strong> away from staple food such as rice, wheat <strong>and</strong> coarse cereals<br />

(Joshi, 2005).<br />

There are several additional merits <strong>and</strong> justifications for favouring diversification<br />

towards high value crops in India. The need for such diversification can be explained on<br />

the basis <strong>of</strong> supply <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> side conditions in the agricultural sector. On the basis <strong>of</strong><br />

supply side conditions, the major factor that raises the need for diversification is the poor<br />

perfonnance <strong>of</strong> agricultural sector in the recent past. With different patterns <strong>of</strong> change in<br />

cropping, a distinct growth pattern in the agricultural sector is observed in India. Prior to<br />

the introduction <strong>of</strong> Green Revolution, the growth in agricultural sector was poor (RudrB,<br />

1982). Slow growth in technology, poor input <strong>and</strong> output markets as well as diversity in<br />

the cropping sector were responsible for slow growth during this period. The post Green<br />

Revolution period saw some improvement in the growth <strong>of</strong> the agricultural secto,-2. This<br />

trend continued until mid 1990s, after which the growth <strong>of</strong> agricultural sector in India<br />

plummeted (Ch<strong>and</strong>, 2006). Structural changes brought about during the 1990s <strong>and</strong><br />

economic reforms in agriculture could not improve the situation significantly.<br />

Surprisingly, not only has the agricultural growth registered an abysmally poor growth<br />

after mid 1990, the lowest decadal growth in the post-independence history but<br />

, However, several studies also argue that growth during 1970s <strong>and</strong> 1980. was reslric1ed only to particular<br />

crops <strong>and</strong> that too in particular regions only (Rao, 1971).<br />

10


agricultural production during this period also remained highly volatile compared to the<br />

19808.<br />

Several studies blame the policy initiatives <strong>of</strong> the past for the present picture <strong>of</strong><br />

gloom in the agricultural sector (Hazra, 2003, <strong>and</strong> Rudra, 1982). It is argued that Green<br />

Revolution was a successful experiment in increasing the level <strong>of</strong> food production, but<br />

despite achieving self-sufficiency in production <strong>of</strong> food grains, the emphasis on cereal<br />

production over the last three decades has also resulted in low output prices <strong>and</strong><br />

pr<strong>of</strong>itability for cereals, which led to dampened agricultural growth (Barghouti et aI.<br />

2004). The recent trend <strong>of</strong> stagnation in productivity <strong>of</strong> these crops with increase in cost<br />

<strong>of</strong> production is making these crops un-remunerative <strong>and</strong> hence affecting the income <strong>of</strong><br />

farmers adversely (Evenson et al. 1999). This is primarily because the post Green<br />

Revolution period saw a shift in the cropping pattern in agricultural sector towards crops<br />

that have registered higher growth in the yield. This process is characterized as<br />

technology-led diversification 3 • As significant acreage was shifted towards selected foodgrain<br />

crops like rice, wheat <strong>and</strong> maize, it led to the emergence <strong>of</strong> specialisation in many<br />

states. The recent years have witnessed stagnancy in the yields <strong>of</strong> many <strong>of</strong> these food<br />

crops that adversely affected the growth rate <strong>of</strong> output <strong>of</strong> specialized states. Not only that<br />

the cost <strong>of</strong> production <strong>of</strong> many <strong>of</strong> the food crops have also been increasing over a period<br />

<strong>of</strong> time, affecting remuneration <strong>of</strong> these crops (Singh <strong>and</strong> Sidhu, 2004, <strong>and</strong> Sidhu, 2(02).<br />

The increased tendency towards specialisation has further resulted in the emergence<br />

<strong>of</strong> environmental concerns <strong>and</strong> sustainability issues, which also hinges on the need for<br />

diversifYing cropping pattern. Specialisation has led to over-exploitation <strong>and</strong><br />

unsustainable use <strong>of</strong> natural resources, due to which many regions are now grappling<br />

with the problems <strong>of</strong> environmental degradation (Joshi, 2001). L<strong>and</strong> degradation due to<br />

factors like soil erosion, water logging <strong>and</strong> application <strong>of</strong> chemicals, several outcomes<br />

like depletion <strong>of</strong> underground water, outbreak <strong>of</strong> new diseases <strong>and</strong> pests <strong>and</strong> water<br />

contamination have become widespread. These developments have depleted the natural<br />

) Green Revolution has helped Indian farmers to increase the output through better use <strong>of</strong> inputs <strong>and</strong> High<br />

yielding varieties (HYV) that helped increasing productivities <strong>of</strong> crops. In other words, technological<br />

devefopment was the: major source <strong>of</strong> growth in output.<br />

II


esource base for agricultural production <strong>and</strong> future growth. It is certain that any future<br />

strategy <strong>of</strong> agricultural development has to strike a balance with environmental <strong>and</strong><br />

ecological concerns in the interest <strong>of</strong> long-term well being <strong>of</strong> the people. As rising<br />

population pressure has been squeezing agricultural l<strong>and</strong> for cultivation (Joshi et al..<br />

2006) <strong>and</strong> several states in India are now hitting the upper limit in use <strong>of</strong> fertilizers <strong>and</strong><br />

irrigation (Ch<strong>and</strong>, 2005). there is a need to look for diversification towards high value<br />

crops as a policy option. In other words. diversification with its emphasis on increased<br />

food grain production has led to environmental problems, <strong>and</strong> making farmers more<br />

vulnerable to weather <strong>and</strong> market risks.<br />

Additionally. there are concerns was related to equity in the agricultural sector <strong>of</strong><br />

Indian economy. as there has been duality in growth across regions 4 • The present<br />

scenario is that while the net income <strong>of</strong> farmers in the developed regions is declining<br />

continuously, farmer's income in developing regions is either stagnant or declining<br />

(Ch<strong>and</strong> 1996). In the recent past, many <strong>of</strong> the developed regions that benefited from the<br />

Green Revolution have experienced poor growth. The major challenge before policy<br />

makers is that now both developed <strong>and</strong> underdeveloped regions are facing the problem <strong>of</strong><br />

low growth. Therefore, there is a need to fmd a conunon model for both the regions to<br />

accelerate growth. It is argued that most <strong>of</strong> the regions that attained high growth in the<br />

past were beneficiaries <strong>of</strong> high subsidization <strong>of</strong> inputs, which the government is<br />

increasingly fmding difficult to provide. besides being unjustifiable in the present era <strong>of</strong><br />

globalization (Ch<strong>and</strong>, 2004). The need <strong>of</strong> the hour is to provide support to developed as<br />

well as underdeveloped regions in order to achieve short <strong>and</strong> long-term goals like higher<br />

income. growth, employment <strong>and</strong> environmental conservation.<br />

Another factor that promotes diversification is the changing economic <strong>and</strong> trade<br />

scenario. Both, annual real rates <strong>of</strong> gross capital formation <strong>and</strong> public investment in the<br />

agriculture sector witnessed a sharp declining trend during the 1990s (Ch<strong>and</strong>. 2004 <strong>and</strong><br />

2006). The policy shifts in terms <strong>of</strong> liberalizing agricultural sector further brought about<br />

.. Only some developed regions (in terms <strong>of</strong> infrastructure like irrigation, proximity to market <strong>and</strong> roads)<br />

were able to grow faster as compared to other regions. The tcchnological change experienced in Indian<br />

agriculture during the last three decades has produced two distinct patterns <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>and</strong> development,<br />

which resulted in duality in tenns <strong>of</strong> developed <strong>and</strong> underdeveloped regions.<br />

12


additional challenges to the sector like price volatility, price decline, increased<br />

competition <strong>of</strong> most food-grains, <strong>and</strong> declining investment in agriculture sector. The<br />

growth rate <strong>of</strong> agriculture has become stagnant <strong>and</strong> more volatile in the postliberalization<br />

era. The diversification away from the food-grain towards high value crops<br />

is also supported by fast improving technology. New production technologies <strong>and</strong><br />

management techniques, such as improved agricultural machinery, biotechnology, new<br />

pest <strong>and</strong> disease contml products, etc. have enabled better use <strong>of</strong> the sources <strong>of</strong><br />

competitive advantage <strong>of</strong> several regions. Technological advances in communication,<br />

logistics, <strong>and</strong> marketing systems have induced supply-side growth <strong>of</strong> non-food crops<br />

(Joshi, 20051. In sum up, the decline in agricultural growth during 19905 is attributed to<br />

increased pattern <strong>of</strong> specialisation <strong>and</strong> higher orientation towards a few food grains. The<br />

recent stagnancy in food grains productivity, incomplete agricultural transformation <strong>and</strong><br />

fatigue in major components <strong>of</strong> growth including area <strong>and</strong> productivity highlights the<br />

need for diversification towards high value crops.<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> in favour <strong>of</strong> high value crops is also desirable due to several<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>-side factors. The present stage <strong>of</strong> poor performance in agriculture along with<br />

structural changes taking place provided a new opportunity for diversification. In other<br />

words, stimulus for diversification came not only from the problems created by overemphasis<br />

on food-grain economy in the past but also because <strong>of</strong> the fast increasing<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> for high value crops including horticultural crops <strong>and</strong> increasing export<br />

opportunities abroad.<br />

Sustained economic growth, rising per capita income <strong>and</strong> growing urbanization<br />

have resulted in increased dem<strong>and</strong> for high-value food commodities like fruits,<br />

vegetables, dairy, poultry, meat <strong>and</strong> fish products from staple food such as rice, wheat<br />

<strong>and</strong> coarse cereals. This is evident from the share <strong>of</strong> these commodities in the total<br />

expenditure on food which increased from 34 percent in 1983 to 44 percent in 1999-2000<br />

in rural areas, <strong>and</strong> from 55 to 63 percent in the urban areas (Kumar <strong>and</strong> Mruthyunjaya,<br />

2(02). In addition, trade liberalization <strong>and</strong> overall higher growth in the economy have<br />

resulted in higher remuneration from many non-food-grain crops due to changes in the<br />

trade scenario <strong>and</strong> changing consumption pattern towards high value crops. Increased<br />

13


liberalization, declining public support <strong>and</strong> poor relative growth in the agriculture sector<br />

have thrown up new concerns. Policy makers are seeking ways to change the way<br />

agriculture sector operates in India works in order to remove inconsistencies <strong>and</strong> achieve<br />

better levels <strong>of</strong> food security for poor <strong>and</strong> malnourished people. This calls for alternative<br />

production systems or strategies to generate new employment, growth <strong>and</strong> higher<br />

incomes. On such a backdrop, diversification <strong>of</strong> agriculture towards high value crops like<br />

fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables is suggested as a viable solution to stabilize <strong>and</strong> raise farm income,<br />

enhance agricultural growth, increase employment opportunities <strong>and</strong> conserve natural<br />

resources (Vyas, 1996 <strong>and</strong> Joshi, 2(05).<br />

It is noted that though diversification per se is not a new phenomenon. At present,<br />

diversification is considered as policy initiative to tackle or improve the situation in the<br />

agricultural sector. It is now emerging as an important option because <strong>of</strong> several key<br />

developments in the economy such as booming economy, changing consumption pattern<br />

towards non-staple crops both in the rural <strong>and</strong> urban areas, trade liberalization <strong>and</strong><br />

declining public support. In this context, diversification is seen mainly as a shift in<br />

cropping pattern from low value crops towards high value crops <strong>and</strong> higher allocation <strong>of</strong><br />

l<strong>and</strong> to high value crops at any given point <strong>of</strong> time. Among the high value crops in India,<br />

horticultural crops comm<strong>and</strong> high value not only in terms <strong>of</strong> their potential in generating<br />

income <strong>and</strong> employment, but also on the basis <strong>of</strong> export-earning opportunities. The future<br />

prospects <strong>of</strong> the horticultural sector are also bright thanks to the changing consumption<br />

pattern towards horticultural crops. Additionally, rising per capita income, growing<br />

urbanization <strong>and</strong> liberalization <strong>of</strong> the economy have led to increase in internal dem<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> export opportunities for horticultural crops.<br />

1.4 <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> as a <strong>Case</strong> for <strong>Diversification</strong> in India<br />

In India, dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops5 <strong>and</strong> their export opportunities have been<br />

continuously increasing. It is felt that the relative significance <strong>of</strong> the crops which are<br />

becoming highly remunerative due to price factor, especially horticultural crops, should<br />

be increased in the cropping pattern mix, as there is a positive nexus between an increase<br />

, Fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables forms the largest sub-sector <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops<br />

14


in the relevance <strong>of</strong> such crops <strong>and</strong> growth in overall output (Joshi et a1., 2006 <strong>and</strong> Birthal<br />

et a1., 2(07). The dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables are increasing at a greater .pace than<br />

other crops. The data on consumption pattern <strong>of</strong> people in India show that there has been<br />

a constant increase in dem<strong>and</strong> for fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables (F& V) as compared to other<br />

crops. The per capita consumption <strong>of</strong> fruits was estimated at 25 kg which increased to<br />

approximately to 40 kg in 200 I, an increase <strong>of</strong> 60% in the last two decades. The annual<br />

per capita consumption <strong>of</strong> vegetables increased from 47 kg in 1983 to 76 kg in 1999<br />

(Singh et a1., 20(4). The overall increase in vegetable consumption was about 53%<br />

during this period. Given the population base <strong>and</strong> the fact that real per capita income<br />

levels have increased at the rate <strong>of</strong> 3.4% per year in between 1981 <strong>and</strong> 1999, the<br />

household expenditure on F&V increased at 5% per annum. Not only this, it is also<br />

expected that the consumption <strong>of</strong> fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables will continue to increase in future<br />

as well; dem<strong>and</strong> for F& V is expected to increase from 98 Million Tonnes (MT) to 220<br />

MT by 2020, assuming a population growth <strong>of</strong> 1.7% per annum <strong>and</strong> commitment for<br />

exports (Singh et aI., 20(4). Among the many high value products like egg, milk, fish,<br />

rice, wheat, it is the fruit <strong>and</strong> vegetable crops whose dem<strong>and</strong> is expected to increase the<br />

most until 2030 in India (table 1.1).<br />

In addition, since horticultural crops are labour-intensive <strong>and</strong> generate high <strong>and</strong><br />

quick returns, these provide farmers a chance to utilize their surplus labour <strong>and</strong> augment<br />

their incomes (Birthal et a1., 2(07). <strong>Horticultural</strong> crops have been acclaimed as a special<br />

case for diversification on several other counts as well. The increased trend towards<br />

specialisation in cropping pattern in few states coupled with stagnancy in their yields <strong>and</strong><br />

increasing cost <strong>of</strong> production is bringing down the real income <strong>of</strong> the farmers. This<br />

highlights the need to look for alternative cropping pattern with a view to remedy the<br />

situation. Due to higher returns <strong>and</strong> productivity <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops, this group<br />

emerged as an important area for diversification <strong>and</strong> as an alternative cropping pattern.<br />

Available evidence shows that one hectare under horticultural crops can generate an<br />

annual income up to Rs. 20,000, compared to hardly Rs. 10000 <strong>and</strong> Rs. 4000 by rice <strong>and</strong><br />

ragi respectively (Singh et a1., 20(4). Cultivation <strong>of</strong> fruits can generate employment to<br />

the tune <strong>of</strong> 860 man-days as against 143 man-days for cereals. <strong>Diversification</strong> towards<br />

15


horticulturaI crops is expounded as the strength <strong>of</strong> Indian agriculture, due to its potential<br />

to produce a wide variety <strong>of</strong>horticulturaI crops under varied. agro-climatic conditions.<br />

Table 1 . l' . Dem<strong>and</strong> for Various Foods in India- 2015 <strong>and</strong> 2030<br />

Foods Year 2015 Y •• r 2030<br />

LIG I-llG LIG I-llG<br />

Rite 101886 101441 114499 113893<br />

Wheat 74607 72411 83045 80087<br />

Pulses 21303 22578 24515 26312<br />

Foodgrains 235399 232547 263752 259993<br />

Edible Oils 10355 10863 11870 12581<br />

Vegetables 123824 151861 150823 193562<br />

Fruits 69678 84099 84336 106126<br />

Milk 109092 127805 130502 158325<br />

Meat 8196 10396 11181 13534<br />

Eggs 2889 3664 3566 4770<br />

Fish 8460 10731 10444 13971<br />

Note:<br />

(i). LIG is Low Income Group (3.5 Per cent pc:r capita GDP) <strong>and</strong><br />

(ii) HIG is High Income Group (5.5 per cent pc:r capita GDP)<br />

Source: Rao, 2003<br />

Currently, India produces about 70 varieties <strong>of</strong> vegetables <strong>and</strong> equally diverse<br />

variety <strong>of</strong> fruits, which consists <strong>of</strong> 70% tropical <strong>and</strong> sub-tropical type <strong>and</strong> the remaining<br />

30010 <strong>of</strong> temperate type. This large <strong>and</strong> varied production base <strong>of</strong>fers an opportunity to<br />

exp<strong>and</strong> domestic <strong>and</strong> overseas markets for horticultural produce. A trend in the increase<br />

volume <strong>of</strong> international trade <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops is also realiZed. World production <strong>of</strong><br />

fiuit <strong>and</strong> vegetables grew by 30 % between 1980 <strong>and</strong> 1990 <strong>and</strong> 56 % between 1990 <strong>and</strong><br />

2003. World trade in fiuits <strong>and</strong> vegetables, both fresh <strong>and</strong> processed, increased by 30 %<br />

since 1990, <strong>and</strong> reached $71.6 billion in 2001. Taking all fiuit <strong>and</strong> vegetable products<br />

together, the value <strong>of</strong> world trade grew at 2-3 percent a year during the 1990s (Diop <strong>and</strong><br />

Jaffee, 2005). There is an opportunity for India to participate <strong>and</strong> join h<strong>and</strong>s with many<br />

countries that have benefited enormously from increasing the share <strong>of</strong> horticultural<br />

production.<br />

1.5 Research Issues<br />

The studies dealing with diversification cover a wide range <strong>of</strong> aspects <strong>and</strong> there are<br />

m!-nad ways to interpret the significance <strong>of</strong> changing trends in diversification. At the<br />

16


macro level, the major debate is about the quantification <strong>and</strong> significance <strong>of</strong> crop<br />

diversification in growth <strong>of</strong> output. As noted earlier, there are several sub-components <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification <strong>and</strong> each component affects growth in different ways. In terms <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification towards high value crops, many researchers have argued that a silent<br />

revolution <strong>of</strong> shift in cropping pattern towards high value crops is already under way<br />

(Joshi, 2006, Vyas, 1996, Ch<strong>and</strong>, 2005, Rao et al, 2004, Birthal et al,. 2(07). But, how<br />

the process <strong>of</strong> diversification has affected the growth <strong>of</strong> output in India. While dealing<br />

with this issue, many studies have dealt with the static aspects <strong>of</strong> diversification, without<br />

emphasising the dynamic aspect. Actually, diversification affects growth through both<br />

static <strong>and</strong> dynamic effects. A positive static effect <strong>of</strong> diversification would show a shift in<br />

crop pattern in favour <strong>of</strong> high initial productivity crops. This does not capture<br />

development in the technology <strong>of</strong> crops that changes over time <strong>and</strong> may alter relative<br />

values <strong>of</strong> crops. In other words, over-time, the pr<strong>of</strong>itability or relative values <strong>of</strong> crops<br />

does not remain constant <strong>and</strong> change in the productivity <strong>of</strong> crops may change the<br />

comparative advantage <strong>of</strong> the crops. Hence, it is also important to consider the dynamic<br />

effects <strong>of</strong> diversification that capture the concomitant movements <strong>of</strong> yield <strong>and</strong> cropping<br />

pattern change. The dynamic aspect <strong>of</strong> diversification indicates the impact <strong>of</strong> the<br />

combined movements <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>of</strong> crop pattern <strong>and</strong> technological change on<br />

overall output change. A positive signs <strong>of</strong> the dynamic effect <strong>of</strong> diversification is a shift<br />

in crop structure in favour <strong>of</strong> those crops which exhibit relatively higher growth in yield.<br />

Similarly, a negative dynamic effect implies, over-time, a shift in cropping pattern in<br />

favour <strong>of</strong> crops which could not experience higher growth in productivity. The question<br />

here is about the role <strong>of</strong> diversification in the growth <strong>of</strong> output in Indian agricultural<br />

sector i.e., whether the changing cropping pattern has been growth inducive or depressive<br />

<strong>and</strong> what are the factors that have contributed to the nature <strong>and</strong> direction <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification in India.<br />

Any decision-making involved in the process <strong>of</strong> diversification towards high value<br />

crops could be analysed at both macro (state or district) <strong>and</strong> micro (farm) levels. At the<br />

macro level, such decisions are examined on the basis <strong>of</strong> price response models,<br />

introduced by Nerlove (N erlove, 1958), who devised a model relating expected "normal"<br />

I<br />

17


price to past-observed prices. Many studies came later that used Nerlovian model with<br />

some modifications th~t investigated the importance <strong>of</strong> price <strong>of</strong> crop in shaping farmers'<br />

supply response behaviour 6 (Krishna, 1963, Behrman, 1968, De, 2005, Askari <strong>and</strong><br />

Cummings, 1976, Sawant, 1978, Mythili, 2006). However, there are several limitations to<br />

this method <strong>of</strong> analysing changing l<strong>and</strong> allocation decision using macro level data.<br />

Measurement <strong>of</strong> supply response usually requires time series data for quantities, cost<br />

<strong>and</strong> prices. Such data are generally not reliable, available for short duration <strong>and</strong> provide<br />

only partial coverage in terms <strong>of</strong> crops <strong>and</strong> area (Medellin, et al. 1994). A large number<br />

<strong>of</strong> crops especially high value horticultural crops are therefore excluded from the analysis<br />

due to lack <strong>of</strong> reliable time series data in India. Another limitation <strong>of</strong> these models is<br />

regarding identification <strong>of</strong> the competing crop. At any given time, not only two crops<br />

compete with each other for l<strong>and</strong> but there are possibilities <strong>of</strong> many crops competing for<br />

l<strong>and</strong>. In addition, the macro level studies mainly concentrated on price <strong>of</strong> the crop as a<br />

major economic factor in shaping farmers' changing l<strong>and</strong> allocation decision. However,<br />

at the farm level, there exists a difference in endowments <strong>and</strong> access to markets. Price<br />

alone may not be the factor in decision-making; heterogeneity in the resource <strong>and</strong> capital<br />

endowments <strong>of</strong> farmers <strong>and</strong> difference in their access to input <strong>and</strong> output markets also<br />

play a role in decision-making. It could be hypothesized that farmers with relatively<br />

higher level <strong>of</strong> productivity may allocate more l<strong>and</strong> to the crop with lower price<br />

expectations. Hence, it is important to examine the link between price <strong>and</strong> income with<br />

the shifting cropping pattern decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers. The question arises that to what extent<br />

price <strong>and</strong> in\:ome from the crop influence.diversification towards high value crops.<br />

Fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables crops are highly remunerative but are also considered risky<br />

crops. A major feature <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops is that prices <strong>of</strong> these crops fluctuate widely<br />

<strong>and</strong> even within a single season. Lack <strong>of</strong> any support price <strong>and</strong> high perishability <strong>of</strong> the<br />

crops make horticultural growers even more vuInerable to risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty than<br />

growers <strong>of</strong> other high value crops like rice or sugarcane. In the event <strong>of</strong> greater extent <strong>of</strong><br />

risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty, the importance <strong>of</strong> the same is high for farmers while taking l<strong>and</strong><br />

6 S~ppl)l response behaviour is the changing l<strong>and</strong> allocation among different crops due to cbange in<br />

economic values <strong>of</strong> crops.<br />

18


allocation decisions. At the fann level, the concept <strong>of</strong> expectation is generally used in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> a response to uncertainty involved in the production process; fanners' speculate<br />

on different economic outcomes including price, yield <strong>and</strong> income. It is therefore crucial<br />

to examine the link between different expectations including price, yield <strong>and</strong> income in<br />

the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions by the fanners.<br />

Risk also could be considered as a strong behavioural force affecting decisionmaking<br />

in l<strong>and</strong> allocation to food crops <strong>and</strong> commercial crops (Blank, 1990, Braun, 1995<br />

<strong>and</strong> Dercon, 1996). A vital perspective <strong>of</strong> risk is how far <strong>and</strong> how <strong>of</strong>ten returns unable to<br />

reacb a below the mean level <strong>of</strong> return. Risk is also taken as a cost <strong>of</strong> decision in fanners'<br />

decision pertaining to l<strong>and</strong> allocation to high value crops (Roumasset, 1976). The Safety­<br />

First principle (Roy, 1952) accounts for such costs in analyzing fanners' behaviour<br />

towards risk. Due to fluctuation in the components <strong>of</strong> revenue from the crop, one can find<br />

two kinds <strong>of</strong> fanners: the first group would prefer to be on safe side <strong>and</strong> hence their<br />

allocation decisions would be explained by income <strong>and</strong> yield variance <strong>of</strong> the crop, as<br />

relative to the perceived disaster level <strong>of</strong> income <strong>of</strong> the fann household. The second<br />

group constitutes fanners who prefer to take risk in their l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions, <strong>and</strong><br />

undertake risk as their disaster level <strong>of</strong> income remains higher than the mean income<br />

from the crop produced for commercial purposes. The fanners take risk <strong>of</strong> meeting<br />

sufficient food for consumption by increasing the allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> more in favour <strong>of</strong><br />

high value crop against the subsistence crop. But, not all fanners prefer to take such risk<br />

<strong>and</strong> hence keep their l<strong>and</strong> allocation low in favour <strong>of</strong> commercial or high value crops.<br />

They follow the principle <strong>of</strong> 'Safety-First' as they realize low utility from the production<br />

<strong>of</strong> horticultural crops. This <strong>of</strong>ten results in selection <strong>of</strong> low-risk crops that deters higher<br />

l<strong>and</strong> allocation to horticultural crops.<br />

1.6 Research Questions<br />

l. What is the nature <strong>and</strong> extent <strong>of</strong> crop diversification across states in India <strong>and</strong> its<br />

role in the growth <strong>of</strong> output in the agricultural sector?<br />

2. Whether the process <strong>of</strong> crop diversification in India has been growth inducive or<br />

lIepressive?<br />

19


3. What is the relative significance <strong>of</strong> economic <strong>and</strong> non-economic factors m<br />

diversification from food crops to horticultural crops?<br />

4. Whether it is the relative price or relative income that matters more m when<br />

farmers decides to diversify towards horticultural crops?<br />

5. What is the nature <strong>of</strong> price expectations <strong>of</strong> farmers <strong>and</strong> its relationship with other<br />

economic factors such as crop yield, cost <strong>of</strong> production <strong>and</strong> input-use<br />

propensities?<br />

6. What is the relative importance <strong>of</strong> different expectations I.e. price, yield <strong>and</strong><br />

income expectations <strong>of</strong> farmers on their l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions?<br />

7. Are the farmers growing horticultural crops averse to risk or not, <strong>and</strong> what are the<br />

determinants <strong>of</strong> their risk-taking behaviour?<br />

8. Does the higher risk <strong>of</strong> production. <strong>and</strong> consumption hinder l<strong>and</strong> allocation in<br />

favour <strong>of</strong> horticultural crop by the farmers?<br />

1.7 Objectives <strong>of</strong>the Study<br />

I. To investigate the relative role <strong>of</strong> diversification on output growth, <strong>and</strong> growth<br />

inducive or depressive impact <strong>of</strong> changing process <strong>of</strong> crop diversification in India<br />

2. To analyse the nature <strong>of</strong> price expectations <strong>of</strong> the diversified farmers, examine its<br />

relationship with other economic factors <strong>and</strong> identify the role <strong>of</strong> different<br />

expectations <strong>of</strong> price, yield <strong>and</strong> income <strong>of</strong> farmers on their l<strong>and</strong> allocation<br />

decisions<br />

3. To estimate the role <strong>of</strong> overall risk <strong>of</strong> production <strong>and</strong> consumption on the extent<br />

<strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> horticultural crop?<br />

1.8 Sampling <strong>and</strong> Methodology<br />

Among the several facets <strong>of</strong> diversification, we have selected diversification<br />

towards horticultural crops as its major proxy. The measures <strong>of</strong> diversification include<br />

both the spatial <strong>and</strong> temporal aspects. On the basis <strong>of</strong> spatial aspect, diversification is<br />

calculated by l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops. Measures based on temporal<br />

aspect <strong>of</strong> diversification include growth rate in area under horticultural crops <strong>and</strong><br />

20


magnitude <strong>of</strong> crop substitution towards horticultural crops. The criterion <strong>of</strong> selecting field<br />

area is guided by these measures <strong>of</strong> diversification.<br />

A multi-stage purposive sampling procedure was followed in order to select the<br />

state, district, block <strong>and</strong> villages (figure 1.2). The selection was based on them being<br />

representative in diversification towards horticultural crops. <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> was<br />

chosen as a study area. In <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>, the importance <strong>of</strong> horticultural sector in its<br />

agricultural sector is very high (representative in terms <strong>of</strong> value <strong>of</strong> the location quotient<br />

exceeding four) <strong>and</strong> the state experienced moderate to higher growth in area under<br />

horticultural crops over the past three decades. We then selected Shimla district, which<br />

was representative in diversification towards horticultural crops as it experienced highest<br />

substitution <strong>of</strong> area towards horticultural crops <strong>and</strong> maximum allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> to<br />

horticultural crops 7 •<br />

We then collected the last ten year block level data from three major sources­<br />

Directorate <strong>of</strong> Horticulture, Directorate <strong>of</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Directorate <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Records,<br />

to identify the temporal <strong>and</strong> spatial pattern diversification in blocks <strong>of</strong> Shimla district. We<br />

calculated the compound growth rate for important crops from agriculture <strong>and</strong><br />

horticulture sector <strong>and</strong> also measured the magnitude <strong>of</strong> crop substitution from food grains<br />

to horticultural crops, as a mean to identify the degree <strong>and</strong> scale <strong>of</strong> diversification. This<br />

was followed by calculation <strong>of</strong> the proportion <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops in the gross cropped<br />

area <strong>and</strong> diversification indexes <strong>of</strong> blocks.<br />

7 The state <strong>and</strong> district level data analysis is provided in Chapter fouT.<br />

21


Figure 1.2: Map <strong>of</strong> Study Area<br />

......, ..<br />

LOCA nON OF HIMACHAL<br />

PRADESH IN INDIA<br />

_...<br />

•<br />

_1001 ____ "'"<br />

SHIMLA DISTRICT<br />

THEOGBLOCK<br />

!<br />

Source: www.images.google.co.in<br />

22


One block, Theog, was chosen as a study area. The temporal picture <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification <strong>and</strong> horticultural development shows that agricultural crops experienced<br />

negative growth in area in all the blocks <strong>of</strong> ShirnIa in the last 10 years <strong>and</strong> vegetable<br />

sector grew faster than fruit sector (table 1.2). The trend <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> vegetable <strong>and</strong> fruit<br />

sector varies by blocks with Chiragaon turning out as representative in the growth <strong>of</strong><br />

fruits <strong>and</strong> Theog representing the vegetable sector. Theog has been able to reallocate<br />

most <strong>of</strong> the area from food grains or non-horticultural crops towards horticultural crops<br />

(table 1.3). From the spatial picture, it emerges that the most diverse region is Theog,<br />

which has substantial area under vegetables (40%), followed by fruits, especially apple<br />

(2oolo) (figure 1.3). lubbal <strong>and</strong> Nark<strong>and</strong>a blocks specialize in apple with a share <strong>of</strong> 62%<br />

<strong>and</strong> 58% respectively. In Rohru, apple covers 50% <strong>of</strong> area <strong>and</strong> a sizeable area (20%) is<br />

covered by potatoes (20%). Basantpur, Chopal <strong>and</strong> Mashobra blocks have more area<br />

under food grains like maize <strong>and</strong> wheat <strong>and</strong> are least diversified (table 1.4). We<br />

amalgamated gross cropped area under horticultural crops with the diversification index<br />

(Herfindahl) to fmd the representative block in both diversification <strong>and</strong> horticultural<br />

deVelopment. Theog turns out to be representative <strong>and</strong> was chosen as the area <strong>of</strong> study.<br />

Table 1.2: Compound Growth Rates in Area <strong>of</strong> Major Crop Groups in Blocks <strong>of</strong><br />

Shimla 1997-2006 ,<br />

Blocks J\ericulturalcrops* Veeetables Fruits <strong>Horticultural</strong> crops--<br />

Basantpur ·0.72 0.73 1.29 1.23<br />

Chopal ·0.65 ·2.62 0.99 ·0.20<br />

Mashobra ·0.73 3.52 1.39 2.18<br />

Chira2aon -0.63 3.67 1.58 2.63<br />

Rampur ·0.59 -0.73 1.76 1.25<br />

NarkaDda ·2.02 2.81 1.16 1.38<br />

Jubbal -0.57 ·3.15 0.85 0.34<br />

Rohru -1.81 1.32 1.31 1.31<br />

Theog -2.71 3.87 1.26 2.69<br />

Shimla District -1.00 2.00 1.24 1.45<br />

Note: Wheat <strong>and</strong> m3.1ze are the major agncultural crops JO the region<br />

• Agricultural crops constitutes <strong>of</strong> all food <strong>and</strong> non-food grain crops, excluding fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables<br />

•• <strong>Horticultural</strong> crops constitutes <strong>of</strong> all fruit <strong>and</strong> vegetable crops.<br />

Source: Directorate <strong>of</strong> J\griculture <strong>and</strong> Horticulture, Shimla, lIP<br />

23


Table 1.3: Absolute Change in Area under <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> in Blocks <strong>of</strong> Shimla,<br />

1997-2006<br />

Blocks Vejle."bles Fruits HorticullUral crops<br />

Basantpur 25 176 201<br />

Chopal ·193 427 234<br />

Masbobra 416 338 754<br />

Chiragaon 442 594 1036<br />

Ram pur -18 682 664<br />

Nark<strong>and</strong>a 181 691 872<br />

JubbaJ -254 611 357<br />

Robru 383 674 1057<br />

Theog 1953 588 2541<br />

Shim" District 2935 4781 7716<br />

Note:<br />

i Area in Hectare<br />

Source: Directomte <strong>of</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Horticulture, Shiml .. HP<br />

Figure 1_3: Pen:entage <strong>of</strong> Gross Cropped Area under FNits <strong>and</strong><br />

Vegetables in Blocks <strong>of</strong> Shim", 2006<br />

~00r-------------------------------------------------'<br />

j roo<strong>of</strong>------­<br />

I 8)00 j--------------------------­<br />

j 5000 t------------------------.<br />

0>.00 j--------------------------------<br />

I.,oot-----<br />

1<br />

l>Joot---<br />

I ~oo<br />

1000<br />

000<br />

Basanps 0I0pII MaIkJtn R-mp.w Ct\ngIorI N ..,.. Rc:IYu Theog JudIeI HP<br />

......<br />

Source: Directorate <strong>of</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Horticulture, Shimla, HP<br />

24


T a bl e 1.4: <strong>Diversification</strong> Indexes <strong>of</strong> Blocks, 2006<br />

Blod •• nerfindahllodex <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> GCA under horticultural <strong>Crops</strong> D1*PAFV<br />

Ba.an!J>ur 0.784 22.08 0.173<br />

. Chop.1 0.850 32.09 0.273<br />

. Ma.bobra 0.831 37.57 0.312<br />

Cbira2aoR 0.805 40.49 0.326<br />

Rampur 0.840 40.30 0.339<br />

Nark<strong>and</strong>a 0.704 71.24 0.502<br />

JubbaJ 0.676 81.50 0.551<br />

Robru 0.734 79.68 0.585<br />

Th_ 0.819 80.76 0.661<br />

Note.<br />

i. The Value <strong>of</strong> Herfindahllndex range from 0-1, 0 being full concentration <strong>and</strong> I means spread in cropping pattern<br />

ii. GCA is the Gross Cropped Area<br />

iii. DloP AFV is multiplication <strong>of</strong> diversification index with percent <strong>of</strong> area under fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables<br />

Source: Authors calculation on the basis <strong>of</strong> the data obtained from Directorate <strong>of</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong><br />

Horticulture, Sbiml .. HP<br />

Due to the difference in the nature <strong>of</strong> the crops within horticultural sector, four<br />

villages were selected (two villages each for fiuits <strong>and</strong> vegetables) from Theog block, as<br />

these villages (Govai, Sainj, Shilaru <strong>and</strong> S<strong>and</strong>hu) are representatives in diversification<br />

towards fiuits <strong>and</strong> vegetables respectively. The choice <strong>of</strong> villages was based on the<br />

discussion from agricultural <strong>and</strong> horticultural development <strong>of</strong>ficers <strong>of</strong> Theog block. In the<br />

ftrst two villages namely Govai <strong>and</strong> Sainj, vegetables cover 72% <strong>and</strong> 84% <strong>of</strong> the total<br />

gross cropped area respectively. Among vegetables, most <strong>of</strong> the diversification has been<br />

towards cauliflower crop. In villages, Shilaru <strong>and</strong> S<strong>and</strong>hu, fruits are grown at a higher<br />

scale. Apple is the major crop in these villages that covers 85% <strong>and</strong> 89% respectively <strong>of</strong><br />

total cultivated area. Both, cauliflower <strong>and</strong> apple crops were chosen for this study in<br />

examining diversification <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> in favour <strong>of</strong> these horticultural crops. Sample <strong>of</strong> 30<br />

farm bouseholds (120 farmers in total) was drawn from each <strong>of</strong> the four villages<br />

following a stratified <strong>and</strong> proportional r<strong>and</strong>om sample approach 8 •<br />

To address the major objectives <strong>of</strong> the study, primary <strong>and</strong> secondary data are used.<br />

The secondary data covers 30 major crops for the past three decades across 17 states in<br />

India. The decomposition model provided by Minhas <strong>and</strong> Vaidyanathan (1965) is<br />

employed to explain agricultural growth in terms <strong>of</strong> both static <strong>and</strong> dynamic manner. For<br />

II Sirlce, interviews with fanners include recall method, many fanners were found to have given inadequate<br />

linformation. ~ence, re-sampling was done after the completion <strong>of</strong> fanners from the first Jist <strong>of</strong> 120. The<br />

'm, -del <strong>of</strong> stratified <strong>and</strong> proportional r<strong>and</strong>om sample approach was kept intact while designing re-sampling.<br />

~n 10131, 167 farmers were interviewed to cover the complete infonnation from 120 farmers<br />

25


measuring the trend in area expansion <strong>and</strong> substitution, we adopted the method by<br />

Venkataramanan <strong>and</strong> Prahladachar (1980) in measuring gross cropped area elasticities.<br />

To work out the economics <strong>of</strong> vegetable <strong>and</strong> fruit crop, different concepts are used. Farm<br />

Management Studies concepts <strong>of</strong> cost <strong>and</strong> returns are applied for examining economics <strong>of</strong><br />

vegetable crop (cauliflower). We measured the output supply <strong>and</strong> factor dem<strong>and</strong><br />

equations from farm level data <strong>of</strong> cauliflower using the pr<strong>of</strong>it function provided by Lau<br />

<strong>and</strong> Y otopoulos (1972). Only one variable, i.e., labour is treated as a variable factor, as<br />

prices <strong>of</strong> other factors <strong>of</strong> production i.e., fertilizer, chemicals <strong>and</strong> irrigation does not vary<br />

across farmers within the region under study. The current year price <strong>and</strong> expected price<br />

are used in measuring the pr<strong>of</strong>it due to marked difference in prices received by farmers<br />

over any single season. Net Present Value (NPV), Benefit-cost Ratio, Internal Rate <strong>of</strong><br />

Return (IRR) <strong>and</strong> payback period are measured to work out the economics <strong>of</strong> a fruit crop<br />

(apple). For the purpose <strong>of</strong> identifying the relative importance <strong>of</strong> price <strong>and</strong> production<br />

risk, method by Barah <strong>and</strong> Binswanger (1982) is employed where the gross revenue<br />

variability is decomposed into price, yield <strong>and</strong> price-yield interaction components. The<br />

method <strong>of</strong> weighted mean is employed to examine the significance <strong>of</strong> economic <strong>and</strong> noneconomic<br />

factors in diversification decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers. Source <strong>of</strong> diversity in farmers'<br />

response to change in price <strong>of</strong> cauliflower is examined by analysis <strong>of</strong> variance<br />

(ANOVA). Elicitation method is employed to obtain the expectations <strong>of</strong> farmers <strong>of</strong><br />

various economic outcomes from the production <strong>of</strong> the selected horticultural crops.<br />

Farmers' expectations are linked with their socio-ecooomic <strong>and</strong> other characteristics<br />

along with their resource allocation including l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> labour. To account for the role <strong>of</strong><br />

overall risk, including production <strong>and</strong> consumption risk, we measured risk attitudes <strong>of</strong><br />

farmers under a Safety-First framework provided by Roy (1952). Regression models are<br />

used to examine the role <strong>of</strong> risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty 00 l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong><br />

horticultura1 crops by farmers.<br />

1.9 Outline <strong>of</strong> the Study<br />

In addition to the first chapter I.e., Introduction, which covers concepts <strong>and</strong><br />

indicatoIi <strong>of</strong> diversification, gaps, research questions, objectives, sampling details <strong>and</strong><br />

26


methodology, the thesis is organized into seven chapters. Chapter 2 consists <strong>of</strong> review <strong>of</strong><br />

literature. Chapter 3 provides a picture <strong>of</strong> nature <strong>and</strong> extent <strong>of</strong> crop diversification in<br />

India, <strong>and</strong> examines the link between several typologies <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>and</strong><br />

agricultural growth over the past few decades in India. This chapter also analyzes the<br />

relative importance <strong>of</strong> diversification process in affecting the growth <strong>of</strong> output in India,<br />

<strong>and</strong> seeks to test whether crop diversification has been growth inducive or depressive.<br />

Also, outlined in this chapter are the factors responsible for typology <strong>of</strong> diversification in<br />

India. Chapter 4 provides an overview <strong>of</strong> the horticultural sector in India, analyses the<br />

role <strong>of</strong> horticulture crops in the growth <strong>of</strong> agricultural sector in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

presents the economics <strong>of</strong> selected horticultural crops i.e. apple <strong>and</strong> cauliflower. In<br />

Chapter 5, the focus is on examining the process <strong>of</strong> reallocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> from food crops<br />

to the selected horticultural crops. This chapter also explores the factors responsible for<br />

diversity in response to change in prices <strong>of</strong> vegetable crop along with analysing the role<br />

<strong>of</strong> price <strong>and</strong> income on the reallocation <strong>of</strong>l<strong>and</strong> from food crops to selected horticultural<br />

crops. Chapter 6 deals with l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> the selected horticultural crops by<br />

farmers. The role <strong>of</strong> risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty (expectation) in l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong><br />

horticultural crops are analyzed in this chapter. The concluding chapter (chapter 7) details<br />

the conclusion <strong>and</strong> policy implications.<br />

27


Appendix 1.1: Facets <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

The term 'diversification' is used in Several ways <strong>and</strong> in different contexts. It is not<br />

limited to the cropping sector, but used generally in the context <strong>of</strong> overall activities. The<br />

basic theorem <strong>of</strong> diversification is that if returns from two activities are independently<br />

<strong>and</strong> identically distributed, then diversification is said to be optimal with equal<br />

distributions to each <strong>of</strong> the activities. <strong>Diversification</strong> is likely to be optimal for riskaverter,<br />

when returns have equal means but covariance are negative. However, large<br />

positive covariance, large disparities in mean returns (e.g. Scale economies), or resource<br />

constraints may provide incentives for specialisation (Pope <strong>and</strong> Prescott, 1980). Since it<br />

has two different dimensions, there are distinct aspects- "diversification into" <strong>and</strong><br />

"diversification in". There are different levels at which diversification can take place:<br />

1. At sector level (between agriculture <strong>and</strong> other non-agricultural sectors),<br />

2. At sub-sectoral level (between or within sub-sectors like livestock, horticulturaI<br />

crops, fisheries),<br />

3. At producers level (small, medium <strong>and</strong> large farmers),<br />

4. At crop level (annual, perennial or their several combinations),<br />

5. At consumer level (rural <strong>and</strong> urban),<br />

6. At intensification or extensification level (double or multiple cropping) etc (Eisa,<br />

1987).<br />

From an analytical viewpoint, two facets <strong>of</strong> diversification are discemable, i.e.,<br />


the degree <strong>of</strong> development in allied activities including food grain crops, horticultural<br />

crops, livestock sector,_ fisheries sector, <strong>and</strong> forestry sector. Activities outside agricultural<br />

sector, like mining, tourism etc. are included in non-agricultural diversification.<br />

AgriculturaI, non-agricultural <strong>and</strong> crop diversification activities are inter-related <strong>and</strong> form<br />

part <strong>of</strong> a process which needs to be viewed in/our stages. Initially, diversification comes<br />

at the cropping level where it is about a shift away from monoculture. At the second<br />

stage, the farm has more than one ente!prise/crop <strong>and</strong> may produce <strong>and</strong> sell crops at<br />

different times <strong>of</strong> year. At the subsequent stage, diversification is understood as being<br />

mixed farming. Finally, activities beyond agriculture are incorporated into the meaning <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification. Such activities could include on-farm processing, the provision <strong>of</strong> nonagricultural<br />

products <strong>and</strong> services on-farm. In addition, it envisages the use <strong>of</strong> farm<br />

resources for non-agricultural activities. At this fmal stage, diversification may be<br />

considered as unconventionality with respect to traditional farm family type agricultural<br />

activities (Chaplin, 2000). In other words, the concept <strong>of</strong> diversification is <strong>of</strong>ten taken to<br />

mean as a shift away from the production <strong>of</strong> surplus commodities to those which may be<br />

exp<strong>and</strong>ed. This is consistent with non-agricultural literature, <strong>and</strong> explains diversification<br />

as a strategy <strong>of</strong> utilizing excess capacity <strong>of</strong> production factors.<br />

Finally, diversification gets a different meaning at farm level, agricultural sector<br />

<strong>and</strong> at regional or country level <strong>and</strong> therefore the process <strong>of</strong> diversification needs to be<br />

analysed at various levels: individual fields within a single farm, single farm within a<br />

region, region to region, <strong>and</strong> country to country. It is possible that although the country<br />

may be well diversified, individual farmers <strong>and</strong> regions may not be. In other words, even<br />

if the farms in different agro-climatic regions specialize in certain products in which<br />

these regions have a comparative advantage, the aggregate picture may still show higher<br />

level <strong>of</strong> diversification as may be revealed by the food basket <strong>of</strong> the region as a whole.<br />

Appendix 1.2: Indicators <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

There are different ways in which diversification can be measured. Agricultural<br />

diversification can be examined in terms <strong>of</strong> diversity <strong>of</strong> crop <strong>and</strong> non-crop enterprises.<br />

When the emphasis is especially on crop diversification, it ought to be related to diversity<br />

29


in crops including cereals, pulses, fruits, vegetables etc. At the macro level, the important<br />

indi~ators <strong>of</strong> crop diversity can be found out from the share or contribution <strong>of</strong> crops in the<br />

cropping pattern. If we consider diversification as a temporal phenomenon, then the<br />

annual <strong>and</strong> compound growth rates in different crops can be used as an indicator <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification. Crop diversification can also be measured by the changes in cropping<br />

pattern in terms <strong>of</strong> substitution <strong>and</strong> expansion effects on crop area. Substitution effect is<br />

the relative decline in area under some crops <strong>and</strong> the corresponding increase in area under<br />

other alternative crops for a given gross cropped area. Expansion effect is the effect <strong>of</strong><br />

increase in gross cropped area (Venkataramanan <strong>and</strong> Prahladachar, 1980).<br />

At the micro level, the extent <strong>of</strong> diversity can be viewed in terms <strong>of</strong> the number <strong>of</strong><br />

component crops within a farming system <strong>and</strong> the relative shares <strong>of</strong> the component crops<br />

in the total farm income <strong>and</strong> activity. First, crop diversity increases with increase in the<br />

number <strong>of</strong> crops grown. The other notion relates to the relative importance <strong>of</strong> each crop<br />

in the cropping system. From this point <strong>of</strong> view, a more diversified farm is one which<br />

does not depend too heavily on any single crop (Rahman <strong>and</strong> Talukder, 200 I). It is<br />

argued that, perhaps, no farmer in India specializes in a single crop. If a farm generates a<br />

large proportion <strong>of</strong> its total income from a single crop, it cannot be called a diversified<br />

farm. It is in this context that farm management textbooks distinguish between a<br />

specialized <strong>and</strong> diversified farm by using a benchmark <strong>of</strong> 50%. A farm is treated as a<br />

diversified farm if no single product accounts for 50"10 or more <strong>of</strong> the total income<br />

(Acharya, 2003). In addition, different strategies, such as multi-cropping <strong>and</strong><br />

intercropping signify diversification <strong>of</strong> agricultural production at the farm level. Farmers<br />

diversify by growing a variety <strong>of</strong> crops at one time, by growing different crops in<br />

different locations at the same time, or by growing different crops over successive<br />

periods <strong>of</strong> time. It is vital to delineate between the diversification <strong>of</strong> crop area as against<br />

diversification in terms <strong>of</strong> value or income. For the cross-sectional analysis, both net<br />

income <strong>and</strong> crop acreages are potential variables over which to defme diversification.<br />

Apart from the above indicators, there are some indices that are commonly used to<br />

mea5ure diversification <strong>of</strong> the acreage <strong>and</strong> income sources. These include Number <strong>of</strong><br />

30


enterprises, Index <strong>of</strong> maximwn portfolio, Simpson index, Entropy index, Ogive index,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Herfmdahl index, the details <strong>of</strong> which are given in the table below.<br />

Indicators <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

Measure Formula Explanation<br />

Index <strong>of</strong> maximum Max Pi It is a measure <strong>of</strong> concentration <strong>of</strong> most<br />

proportion<br />

dominant activity <strong>and</strong> has a range from 0 to I<br />

where 0 means perfect diversification.<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> N Where I is zero-one indicator, i.e., when Pi<br />

enterprises<br />

exists I takes a value <strong>of</strong> one, if Pi does not<br />

D= L I (P;) exists, I takes a zero value. For increasing<br />

diversification, D increases. D may take a<br />

i=I<br />

value <strong>of</strong> more than one; it takes a value one<br />

when there is complete specialisation.<br />

Herfindahl Index N Pi is the proportion area (or value) <strong>of</strong> the ith<br />

crop in the Gross Cropped Area (GCA). The<br />

HI= 1- L Pi 2 index approaches zero for perfect<br />

specialisation <strong>and</strong> has upper limit <strong>of</strong> one,<br />

i=1 which signifies diversification.<br />

Entropy Index N This index is a weighted swn <strong>of</strong> proportions<br />

[weights being log (llPi)]. It attains 0 with<br />

EI= L Pi . [log (11Pi) complete specialisation <strong>and</strong> log (N) with<br />

perfect diversification. This IS good for<br />

i=1 capturing the 'diversity' aspect <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification as N varies, Thus, it shows<br />

how diversified is a distribution.<br />

Ogivelndex N This index is a measure <strong>of</strong> deviation <strong>of</strong> a<br />

given distribution from an equal distribution<br />

01= L[ {Pi-(IIN)}2/(IIN}] benchmark. It attains 0 with complete<br />

diversification <strong>and</strong> a maximum value (as set<br />

i=1 by N) for complete specialisation. This is<br />

good for reflecting the 'deviation' aspect<br />

when N IS fixed. Thus, it shows how<br />

unbalanced is the distribution.<br />

31


CHAPTER II<br />

REVIEW OF LITERATURE<br />

It is well recognized in the literature that there are several dimensions to<br />

diversification. Therefore, any attempt to review requires systematic arrangement <strong>of</strong><br />

issues. This has to be achieved on the basis <strong>of</strong> its rationale <strong>and</strong> impact on income <strong>and</strong><br />

risk. It can either be a strategy to optimize income or an alternative strategy to deal with<br />

risk or both. These two aspects deal with the farmer's decision making process under the<br />

assumption <strong>of</strong> perfect knowledge. However, it is highly unlikely that such ideal situation<br />

exists <strong>and</strong> hence diversification also has to be a strategy choice to deal with a situation <strong>of</strong><br />

imperfect knowledge or uncertain situation. In addition to separating the positive <strong>and</strong><br />

normative issues <strong>of</strong> diversification, it is necessary to contextualize the view-points<br />

according to various definitions <strong>of</strong> diversification used in various studies. For the purpose<br />

<strong>of</strong> convenience, we have grouped the review under the following broad themes. These<br />

themes are designed keeping in view the need for the present research.<br />

l. Studies dealing with positive issues, i.e., factors affecting diversification that<br />

include drivers <strong>of</strong> <strong>and</strong> constraints on diversification. This section is divided into<br />

three sub-sections according to the definition <strong>of</strong> diversification:<br />

a. <strong>Diversification</strong> as changing l<strong>and</strong> allocation under crops<br />

b. <strong>Diversification</strong> in terms <strong>of</strong> diversity <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern<br />

c. <strong>Diversification</strong> represented as proportion <strong>of</strong> High Value <strong>Crops</strong><br />

2. Studies dealing with normative issues that investigated the link between the risk,<br />

uncertainty <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions<br />

3. Studies examining the role <strong>of</strong> changing typology <strong>of</strong> crop diversification on growth<br />

<strong>of</strong> agriculture<br />

32


2.1. Factors Affecting <strong>Diversification</strong>- Drivers <strong>and</strong> Constraints<br />

2.1.1 <strong>Diversification</strong> as a Changing Allocation <strong>of</strong> Area under<br />

<strong>Crops</strong><br />

The factors affecting decision-making in the allocation <strong>of</strong> area under the crops can<br />

be broadly grouped into the price <strong>and</strong> non-price factors. According to economic theory,<br />

prices influence relative pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>and</strong> play an important role in decision-making. At a<br />

macro level, this is generally articulated with the belp <strong>of</strong> the concept <strong>of</strong> expectations.<br />

Nerlove (1958) initiated study on this aspect to frod the role <strong>of</strong> farmer's expectation <strong>of</strong><br />

future prices in shaping their decisions as to how much l<strong>and</strong> they should devote to crops.<br />

He devised a model relating expected "normal" price to the past-observed prices. The<br />

basic Nerlove model is a simple three-equation model focused on price expectation:<br />

A*t = a. + alP*t + Ut ---------------------------------------------------1<br />

P*t -p* '·1= b (Pt. I - P*t.l) -----------------·--------------------2<br />

A.- At.l = c (A*,- At.l) ----------------------------------------------------3<br />

The fmal equation was<br />

Where At is actual area under cultivation, A *, is desired area to be put under<br />

cultivation, Pt is actual price <strong>of</strong> output, P*t is expected price, Z. is other exogenous factors<br />

affecting supply <strong>and</strong> Ut is the r<strong>and</strong>om disturbance or error. The subtext 't' denotes the<br />

time period t.<br />

The first equation relates to expected future price to the desired planted area. The<br />

second equation indicates that the expected price is the previous year price plus 'b' times<br />

the differellce between the expected <strong>and</strong> realized price. The third equation indicates that<br />

in each period actual planted area is adjusted in proportion to the difference between the<br />

33


planted area <strong>and</strong> desired area. The major problem identified by Ner\ove in his model was<br />

its inability to capture the role <strong>of</strong> technology <strong>and</strong> infrastructure through prices. Following<br />

this. Askari <strong>and</strong> Cummings (1976) attempted to explore the role <strong>of</strong> expected yield in the<br />

supply response model. Their model indicates that the present year crop yield is first the<br />

function <strong>of</strong> past yield. Second, since l<strong>and</strong> quality is not homogenous. use <strong>of</strong> additional<br />

l<strong>and</strong> or reduction in planted acreage could impact average yield. For instance, if inferior<br />

l<strong>and</strong> is bought under cultivation then the average yield is likely to decrease. Thirdly.<br />

shifts in the use <strong>of</strong> non-l<strong>and</strong> inputs such as fertilizer. machinery <strong>and</strong> irrigation facilities as<br />

well as changes in rainfall affect yield. They criticized the original Nerlovian equation on<br />

the count that in a desired acreage equation, the appropriate variable is the expected yield<br />

rather than the actual yield. It is primarily because the farmer does not have priori<br />

knowledge about yield from the crop at the time <strong>of</strong> planting. He rather makes some<br />

independent estimates <strong>of</strong> what the yield is likely to be on the basis <strong>of</strong> change in input use<br />

<strong>and</strong> weather conditions. Significant results were observed by this study after including<br />

the expected yield in the Nerlovian model.<br />

Most <strong>of</strong> the initial analysis in the price response models was restricted to the<br />

developed countries. Behrman (1968) was one among the firsts to analyze the supply<br />

response in the context <strong>of</strong> developing countries. He examined the Nerlovian dynamic<br />

aggregate supply response model using the area planted in a crop as the dependent<br />

'!ariable. The result <strong>of</strong> the study supported the hypothesis that farmers in underdeveloped<br />

countries respond significantly to economic incentives. Institutional constraints do not<br />

seem to have precluded significant response to economic incentives. Later, many studies<br />

also came up in India.<br />

In the case <strong>of</strong> Indian economy, initially, a commonly held view was that Indian<br />

farmers are not price responsive <strong>and</strong> they generally produce for subsistence. This<br />

paradigm was disproved with empirical evidence by Krishna (1963) <strong>and</strong> Narain (I 965).<br />

-They indicated that Indian farmers do respond to prices. Krishna (1963) fitted the acreage<br />

respom,e 1fnction to 11 crops for Punjab. By correctly specifying the relevant non·price<br />

variables like irrigation, yield <strong>and</strong> rainfall, he obtained the elasticities with respect to<br />

price variables. In other words. he included only those variables in the estimating<br />

34


equation <strong>of</strong> a given crop which were found to be important in detennining the acreage <strong>of</strong><br />

that particular crop. Krishna (1963) introduced the concept <strong>of</strong> shifter variable <strong>and</strong><br />

concluded that by correctly specifYing the relevant non-price variables, one can obtain<br />

significant net regression co-efficient <strong>and</strong> elasticities <strong>of</strong> price variable.<br />

Narain (1965) analysed the producer's behaviour in response to price changes,<br />

whereby a graphic comparison <strong>of</strong> the year to year variations in acreage <strong>of</strong> crops with<br />

variation in prices <strong>and</strong> yields was done. The prices <strong>of</strong> competing crops <strong>and</strong> data on<br />

rainfall have also been juxtaposed. He examined farmer responsiveness to prices <strong>and</strong><br />

noted a striking difference in behaviour <strong>of</strong> farmers growing cash crops <strong>and</strong> food crops.<br />

The study concluded that the Indian farmer is responsive to price, but there is a striking<br />

difference <strong>of</strong> behaviour between cash crops <strong>and</strong> food crops. In the case <strong>of</strong> food grains,<br />

rainfall assumes that status which price does in the case <strong>of</strong> cash crops. Cummings (I 975)<br />

analysis <strong>of</strong> the supply response behaviour <strong>of</strong> Indian farmers by using nine crops data for<br />

the period <strong>of</strong> 1949 to 1969 also supported the hypothesis that Indian farmers were aware<br />

<strong>of</strong> market <strong>and</strong> its potential rewards for cash <strong>and</strong> food crops. Sawant (I 972) analysed two<br />

different types <strong>of</strong> supply response <strong>of</strong> paddy crop. The first represents productivity <strong>of</strong><br />

paddy <strong>and</strong> the other relates to acreage under paddy. The results show that the estimates <strong>of</strong><br />

price elasticity for yield per acre were higher than those for the acreage. Also, dominance<br />

<strong>of</strong> small fanners <strong>and</strong> tenant holdings restrain supply response.<br />

The dynamic aspect <strong>of</strong> the decision making process <strong>of</strong> the farmers was studied by<br />

Maji et aI. (\971). They incorporated the risk factor into the Nerlovian model <strong>of</strong> supply<br />

response. The ratio <strong>of</strong> actual st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation <strong>of</strong> the price <strong>of</strong> crop relatively to the<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation <strong>of</strong> the price <strong>of</strong> alternative crop was used as a proxy for relative price<br />

risk. This study was followed by the incorporation <strong>of</strong> relative pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>and</strong> income in<br />

the price responsiveness <strong>of</strong> farmers by Deshp<strong>and</strong>e <strong>and</strong> Ch<strong>and</strong>rashekar (1980). In their<br />

study on growth <strong>and</strong> supply response <strong>of</strong> pulses, they noted the perverse supply response<br />

<strong>of</strong> area under pulses to prices. This motivated them to incorporate the concept <strong>of</strong> income<br />

in the supply response <strong>of</strong> farmers growing pulses <strong>and</strong> other slow growth crops. After<br />

trying several equations to study the supply response behaviour <strong>of</strong> the farmers in the high<br />

growth <strong>and</strong> low growth regions, they found out the positive response <strong>of</strong> these crops to the<br />

IS F. C U:' Rf. "'':' n,v~:: ALORE<br />

Ace. Nu •.• =t1:t J ...... t(i<br />

.~ .~ ,..... ~-<br />

35


eal price <strong>and</strong> income <strong>of</strong> the crop. They suggested that it was mainly the lack <strong>of</strong><br />

technology than the prices that was responsible for the slow growth <strong>of</strong> pulses.<br />

These macro models are based on the assumption that farm decision making is<br />

solely dependent on the parametric prices. This drew criticism as these models<br />

underestimated the role <strong>of</strong> net income. In other words, these models over-emphasized the<br />

role <strong>of</strong> relative prices <strong>and</strong> undennined the role <strong>of</strong> income in the decision-making process.<br />

Second, these models were based on the assumption <strong>of</strong> perfect functioning <strong>of</strong> inputs <strong>and</strong><br />

output markets, which is erroneous to assume, especially in the developing countries.<br />

Third, there is always a problem <strong>of</strong> identifying competing crops. Many a time more than<br />

two crops compete for a l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> hence render the supply responsive model less<br />

significant. In addition, analysis <strong>of</strong> perennial crops was also not touched by these studies<br />

due to lack <strong>of</strong> time series data on these crops in India.<br />

Though, macro models are important for policy fonnulation, underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong><br />

responsiveness to various policy stimuli at the farm level are also <strong>of</strong> great importance.<br />

But, it was expected that the results <strong>of</strong> farm level studies would differ across regions due<br />

to changes in cropping pattern <strong>and</strong> through various time periods. In the context <strong>of</strong> farm<br />

level studies, Johnson (1967) built a theoretical model in which he introduced separation<br />

theorem in order to explain the dynamics <strong>of</strong> decision-making by farmers on combining<br />

risky options with risk-less options. On the basis <strong>of</strong> the assumption that there exists a<br />

risk-free option in terms <strong>of</strong> crops or l<strong>and</strong> leasing, it was demonstrated that this theorem<br />

could be extended to study the impact on l<strong>and</strong> leasing <strong>and</strong> long-run diversification <strong>of</strong> crop<br />

activities. By making use <strong>of</strong> expected net returns <strong>and</strong> variability, one can determine the<br />

optimal enterprises mixes or crops. This model was one <strong>of</strong> the few that planned to<br />

e){amine diversification decision by farmers through objective analysis. Prior to this<br />

study, most <strong>of</strong> the studies, explaining such diversification decisions, were based on<br />

analysis using subjective judgment <strong>of</strong> farmers. However, there is a lack <strong>of</strong> studies on the<br />

empirical examination <strong>of</strong> separation theorem. It is more <strong>of</strong> a theoretical model <strong>and</strong> the<br />

theorem hifS not been verified empirically either by him or others.<br />

36


As noted, in the case <strong>of</strong> price responsiveness <strong>of</strong> fanners, most <strong>of</strong> the studies at the<br />

macro level dealt with supply response in the context <strong>of</strong> developed countries. The major<br />

concern is that models <strong>and</strong> findings in the context <strong>of</strong> developed countries may not be<br />

applicable to developing countries. This is especially so because in developed countries,<br />

almost all crops are produced primarily for commercial purposes. Nowshirvani (1971)<br />

argued against the relevance <strong>of</strong> these models in the context <strong>of</strong> developing countries where<br />

considerable number <strong>of</strong> crops is produced for self-consumption. This study showed that<br />

element <strong>of</strong> risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty caused by fluctuations result in diversification <strong>of</strong><br />

cropping pattern. In other words, diversity in cropping pattern cannot be explained<br />

entirely by the heterogeneity <strong>of</strong> the l<strong>and</strong> or the need to spread labour inputs over the<br />

entire year. Nowshirvani (1971) developed a theoretical model <strong>of</strong> allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong><br />

among different crops when both yield <strong>and</strong> prices are subject to uncertainty. This was<br />

done primarily in order to explore the implications <strong>of</strong> the government policy <strong>of</strong> price<br />

stabilization <strong>and</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> change in expected yields <strong>and</strong> prices on farmers'<br />

diversification decision. The study indicates that price stabilization has bad effect on<br />

farmers' welfare if crop is produced for self consumption. Direction <strong>of</strong> supply response to<br />

change in expected prices may not be positive. There is dramatic difference between cash<br />

<strong>and</strong> food crops <strong>and</strong> inclusion <strong>of</strong> uncertainty makes the direction <strong>of</strong> area-price response<br />

ambiguous in case <strong>of</strong> food crops. This study is significant due to its focus on developing<br />

countries. However, the study remains to be tested empirically.<br />

Until early 1960s, studies on supply response by farmers largely emphasized price<br />

as the major driving force in explaining their behaviour. Later other economic<br />

components viz, price stabilization, income <strong>and</strong> cost factors drew the attention <strong>of</strong> studies<br />

related to diversification. While examining the role <strong>of</strong> price stabilization policy by the<br />

government, Martin et ai, (I %5) evaluated the effect <strong>of</strong> alternative cotton acreage<br />

allotment on price situations. They noted that cotton would be more pr<strong>of</strong>itable even if the<br />

prices were to be below the support price <strong>and</strong> any increase in the allotment acreage level<br />

would result in higher production <strong>of</strong> cotton. But, for some high value crops like cotton,<br />

price polic~ was found to be ineffective in impacting the acreage decisions <strong>of</strong> the<br />

farmers. Therefore, in order to maintain potential income level, cotton production needs<br />

37


igller subsidy payments unless there is a considerable increase m the free market<br />

equilibrium price.<br />

Since prices partially affect the relative pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong> crops, use <strong>of</strong> net income for<br />

decision making in the choice between crops becomes an important issue for discussion.<br />

Imminck <strong>and</strong> Alarcon (1993) examined the role <strong>of</strong> economic <strong>and</strong> non-economic factors<br />

on crop diversification decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers. Use <strong>of</strong> income as an economic factor <strong>and</strong><br />

food availability as non-economic factor, they explored its relation with different crop<br />

mixes including food <strong>and</strong> commercial crops like wheat, potato <strong>and</strong> vegetable. The study<br />

inferred that net returns play an important role in diversification towards commercial<br />

crops. Net income effect <strong>of</strong> crop substitution depends on relative net returns <strong>of</strong> different<br />

crops <strong>and</strong> on the degree <strong>of</strong> crop substitution. Lack <strong>of</strong> market access <strong>and</strong> high fluctuation<br />

in farm output <strong>and</strong> input prices could reduce gross margins substantially <strong>and</strong> lead to<br />

income loss. Therefore, access to credit <strong>and</strong> market playa critically important role in<br />

promoting diversification towards higll value commercial crops.<br />

In addition to the relevance <strong>of</strong> prices <strong>and</strong> income, another aspect i.e. cost <strong>of</strong><br />

obtaining food crop when a food crop is substituted for cash crop, becomes an important<br />

field <strong>of</strong> discussion where studies by Fafchamps (1992), Jayne (I994) <strong>and</strong> Key, et al.<br />

(2000) drew a lot <strong>of</strong> significance. Fafchamps (1992) examined the role <strong>of</strong> food market<br />

integration in reducing the need <strong>of</strong> food-self-sufficiency <strong>and</strong> decision about cash crop<br />

production. He presents a theoretical model <strong>of</strong> crop portfolio choice wherein the revenue<br />

<strong>of</strong> individual crops is correlated with consumption prices. Also, the effects <strong>of</strong><br />

consumption preferences on output choices were examined <strong>and</strong> the possible impact <strong>of</strong><br />

market integration on optimal crop choices simulated. The study found that as<br />

agricultural productivity increased, per unit transport cost goes would go down <strong>and</strong> socioeconomic<br />

factors would have less affect on crop choice decisions. The logic <strong>of</strong> this<br />

explanation is that improvement in market <strong>and</strong> reduction in transport cost equalizes price<br />

movements across a larger regional or intemational market. In other words, food market<br />

integrallo\l would reduce price variance <strong>and</strong> the correlation between individual output<br />

<strong>and</strong> aggregate supply. Thus, is likely to increase the market price elasticity <strong>of</strong> food<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> decrease the correlation between crops -:evenue. These effects combine<br />

38


together to decrease small farmers' need to rely on their own food production which<br />

weakens the individual aspiration for food self- sufficiency. Jayne (1994) demonstrated<br />

that high food marketing costs encourage household self-sufficiency <strong>and</strong> limited cash<br />

crop production in Zimbabwe. The study brought out that not only returns from the high<br />

value crops matter for diversification decision by forgoing food crop but also the cost <strong>of</strong><br />

obtaining the food crop drive the decision <strong>of</strong> farmers to choose high value crops. The<br />

study grouped farmers on the basis <strong>of</strong> grain deficit <strong>and</strong> grain surplus, to analyse the role<br />

<strong>of</strong> food self-sufficiency on diversification towards commercial crops. It is argued that<br />

cash crop production might be economically unviable for diversification decision <strong>of</strong><br />

farmers despite higher returns <strong>of</strong> commercial crops to l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> labour. It is the level <strong>of</strong><br />

food self-sufficiency that matters more for increasing l<strong>and</strong> allocation to commercial crop.<br />

Key et al. (2000) used household data to explain how fixed <strong>and</strong> variable transaction costs<br />

that includes the time to sell the crop in the market <strong>and</strong> distance to market is affecting the<br />

maize supply response <strong>of</strong> rural households.<br />

There was also emphasis on non-price factors in the diversification decisions.<br />

Lichtenberg (1989) examined the interaction between l<strong>and</strong> quality, crop choice <strong>and</strong><br />

technological change. The study indicated that acreage allocated to different crops vary<br />

significantly over l<strong>and</strong> quality. <strong>Crops</strong> tend to be grown on specific types <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> quality<br />

<strong>and</strong> the introduction <strong>of</strong> pivot technology induced significant changes in cropping patterns.<br />

In another interesting study, Kurosaki (2005) investigated the impact <strong>of</strong> agricultural<br />

policies on fann production decisions <strong>and</strong> rural incomes in rural Myanmar. In this<br />

analysis, paddy was considered as a lucrative or diversified crop <strong>and</strong> other crops are<br />

considered as non-lucrative crops. The study showed that the acreage share <strong>of</strong> nonlucrative<br />

paddy is higher for farmers who were under tighter control <strong>of</strong> the local<br />

authorities. The government policies that put unwarranted or disproportionate emphasis<br />

on paddy crop with low income per acre end up in sub-optimal use <strong>of</strong> agricultural<br />

resources in Myanmar <strong>and</strong> act as a constraint to diversification towards other crops.<br />

In stjrn, studies that concentrated on crop reallocation decisions <strong>and</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> crops<br />

are at the core <strong>of</strong> analyses. The short-term <strong>and</strong> long-term elasticities <strong>of</strong> supply response to<br />

prices are computed to gauge the relevance <strong>of</strong> price in changing l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions<br />

39


y farmers. However, several lacunae associated with the models drew criticisms against<br />

using these models f~r supply response, especially in the context <strong>of</strong> developing countries.<br />

A large number <strong>of</strong> crops, particularly high value crops including horticultural crops have<br />

been excluded from the studies. Furthermore, only price is considered in the response <strong>of</strong><br />

farmers <strong>and</strong> income potential <strong>of</strong> the crop is mainly ignored in analysing such decision<br />

making. Price alone may not be the only factor in decision-making. Heterogeneity in the<br />

resources, capital endowments <strong>of</strong> the farmers, difference in access to input <strong>and</strong> output<br />

market by the farmers are other important factors. Such difference influences prices <strong>and</strong><br />

productivity <strong>of</strong> the crop <strong>and</strong> hence income attained at the farm level.<br />

2.1.2. <strong>Diversification</strong> in terms <strong>of</strong> Diversity in the Cropping<br />

Pattern<br />

Over a period <strong>of</strong> time, resource allocation to crops can change in rwo different<br />

ways: 1) the amount <strong>of</strong> resources to crops can be increased <strong>and</strong> 2) the amount <strong>of</strong><br />

resources can be held constant while shifting a part <strong>of</strong> them to other crops. The first<br />

system has ramifications closely related to the capital <strong>and</strong> increasing risk considerations,<br />

whereas the second system has more widespread application since most farmers have<br />

limited l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> capital (Heady, 1952). Most studies concentrate on the second system <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification, where diversity <strong>and</strong> spread in the cropping pattern are used as proxy for<br />

diversification.<br />

IS<br />

The expected trade-<strong>of</strong>f berween specialisation <strong>and</strong> diversity in the cropping pattern<br />

the major area <strong>of</strong> debate in literature. The relation berween farm size <strong>and</strong><br />

diversification is an indicator <strong>of</strong> trade-<strong>of</strong>fs berween risk reduction <strong>and</strong> possible<br />

economies <strong>of</strong> scale due to specialisation in a particular crop. That is, if there are not<br />

substantial economies <strong>of</strong> scale in a particular crop if one specializes in that crop, one<br />

clearly gives up a large expected return in order to insure against risk through<br />

diversification (Pope <strong>and</strong> Prescott, 1980). In other words, increase in the level <strong>of</strong> diversity<br />

<strong>of</strong> the cropping pattern is contingent upon the condition that gain from diversification<br />

will <strong>of</strong>fset gain from specialisation. By diversifying, the farm sacrifices economies <strong>of</strong><br />

40


scale or income, but tends to stabilize returns at a lower level with the benefits <strong>of</strong> risk<br />

reduction (White <strong>and</strong> Irwin, 1972). Thus, if risk management motivates diversification,<br />

the average income comes down. <strong>Diversification</strong> can reduce risk <strong>and</strong> smoothen the<br />

consumption in the face <strong>of</strong> weather <strong>and</strong> market shocks (Reardon, et a1. \988). Thus,<br />

diversification is expected to occur when income sources are highly variable <strong>and</strong><br />

households are particularly risk averse. This may be one <strong>of</strong> the reasons why poor rural<br />

households practicing rain-fed agriculture in low-potential areas are more likely to have<br />

diverse cropping pattern than richer households in areas with greater agro-ecological<br />

potential (Minot et al. 2006). According to the study by Koukebene et a1. (1996), at low<br />

level <strong>of</strong> risk aversion, farmers increases investment in <strong>of</strong>f-farm activities <strong>and</strong> prefer to<br />

specialize in few crops like soyabean or com crops. The study fmds the policy <strong>of</strong><br />

government support responsible to higher levels <strong>of</strong> specialisation.<br />

Empirically examining the hypothesis <strong>of</strong> the income-risk trade-<strong>of</strong>f, Johnson <strong>and</strong><br />

Brester (200 I) argues that the decision to diversify by farmer can be explained by<br />

effective economic diversification. According to them, three primary economic<br />

considerations are important when a farm manager contemplates increasing diversity in<br />

the cropping pattern through the introduction <strong>of</strong> alternative crop. These are; I) Will the<br />

alternative crop be a pr<strong>of</strong>itable crop?, 2) Will the introduction <strong>of</strong> alternative crop result in<br />

some positive impact in terms <strong>of</strong> increase in net farm income?, <strong>and</strong> 3) Will the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> alternative crop result in economic diversification? The decision <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification is economic in two conditions i.e. when by diversification, farmer gets the<br />

same net fann income with less year-to-year variability in income or when it increases<br />

the farm income with same or an acceptable level <strong>of</strong> increase in income variability. The<br />

study supported the hypothesis that farmers' decision <strong>of</strong> diversification depends primarily<br />

on the condition <strong>of</strong> effective economic diversification.<br />

The comparison <strong>of</strong> risk with farm income was one aspect <strong>of</strong> examining factors<br />

responsible for diversification. However, these studies ignored the relationship between<br />

risk <strong>and</strong> major costs in production <strong>of</strong> crops that also may influence diversification<br />

decisions. In this line <strong>of</strong> thought, Nartea <strong>and</strong> Barry (1994) examined the effects <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification on the variance <strong>of</strong> farm rates <strong>of</strong> return, <strong>and</strong> on transportation, monitoring<br />

41


<strong>and</strong> other operating costs. Their results indicate that risk reduction from diversification in<br />

Illinois is relatively small <strong>and</strong> is more than <strong>of</strong>fset by increased operating costs. Rather<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> for l<strong>and</strong> is the major motivation for observed levels <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>of</strong> farmers.<br />

But, they warned that their conclusion only applies to Illinois <strong>and</strong> one may get different<br />

results in other geographical areas.<br />

As farm size influence income, risk <strong>and</strong> cost in the production <strong>of</strong> crops, it was<br />

expected that farm size greatly influence capacity to diversify by farmers. Pope <strong>and</strong><br />

Prescott (1980) revealed a negative relation between farm size <strong>and</strong> specialisation.<br />

According to them, experience, price risks, wealth <strong>and</strong> education are few <strong>of</strong> the<br />

constraints for diversification. It was noted that an individual's likelihood <strong>of</strong> participating<br />

in a risky project increases with wealth <strong>and</strong> thus, large & wealthier farms tend to exhibit a<br />

propensity to specialize. This was attributed to the fact that wealthier farmers were less<br />

risk-averse. This argument challenged the fmdings <strong>of</strong> White <strong>and</strong> Irwin (1972), who got a<br />

positive relation between farm size <strong>and</strong> specialisation. The difference in results <strong>of</strong> these<br />

studies was attributed to different definitions <strong>of</strong> diversification used by them. However,<br />

later some researcher also challenged the relation between farm size <strong>and</strong> diversification<br />

on the basis in which farm size is defmed. By changing the way in which farm size is<br />

defined Pagoulatos et al (1987) noted an inverse relation between farm size <strong>and</strong> level <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification. They used farm acreage as an indicator <strong>of</strong> farm size. According to their<br />

study, as diversification increases, farm income per acre increase substantially <strong>and</strong> small<br />

farmers need not necessarily be more diversified than large fanners.<br />

Singh (1996) differentiated between diversity in crop <strong>and</strong> plot diversity in order to<br />

examine the link <strong>of</strong> different types <strong>of</strong> diversity with economic <strong>and</strong> non-economic factors.<br />

According to him, larger l<strong>and</strong> holdings are associated only with plot diversification <strong>and</strong><br />

not with crop diversification. However, plot diversification does not <strong>of</strong>fer significant<br />

protection against instability in gross crop returns. Both crop <strong>and</strong> plot diversifications are<br />

not strongly correlated with mean levels <strong>of</strong> household net crop income. Interestingly, he<br />

illustrated that the impact <strong>of</strong> irrigation on crop diversification <strong>and</strong> income stability is<br />

dependant upon cropping conditions <strong>and</strong> the level <strong>of</strong> irrigation. When expansion <strong>of</strong><br />

irrigation takes place in an assured rainfall region, it leads to more crop specialisation in<br />

42


paddy production. In contrast, when an investment in well irrigation occurs in a dry-l<strong>and</strong><br />

region, it enhances opportunities for further crop diversification. Hence, the role <strong>of</strong><br />

irrigation on crop specialisation or diversification depends on regional factors. In<br />

conclusion, it was noted that crop <strong>and</strong> plot diversification fluctuation was more in<br />

drought prone regions <strong>and</strong> crop diversification was more sensitive to agro-climatic<br />

determinants than plot diversification.<br />

There was a well-established belief that commercialization fostered specialisation.<br />

This was first challenged by Gregson (\994). He hypothesized that diversification was a<br />

function <strong>of</strong> labour availability, risk due to unstable prices <strong>and</strong> soil diversitY. In other<br />

words, the crop mix decision is a function <strong>of</strong> farm gate prices <strong>and</strong> farmer's agronomic<br />

endowment lO <strong>and</strong> overtime, farmers' decision to plant a new crop is influenced by<br />

increasing dem<strong>and</strong>, falling transport cost <strong>and</strong> the suitability <strong>of</strong> soil for the crop. The study<br />

found that other than distance from market, the geography <strong>of</strong> the farm had little effect on<br />

crop choice when transport cost was high. But, when transport costs falls, the<br />

geographical locations <strong>of</strong> farms becomes a factor in crop choice. He concludes that<br />

commercialization need not necessarily lead to higher specialisation <strong>and</strong> it can lead to<br />

higher level <strong>of</strong> diversification. In another study, Gregson (1996) notes that change in the<br />

crop mix is a function <strong>of</strong> relative pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong> crops due to less cost or high revenue.<br />

Higher specialisation takes place by more fertilizer use as it allows farmers to get higher<br />

<strong>and</strong> stable income. In other words, more use <strong>of</strong> fertilizer lead farmers away from<br />

diversified farming to a more specialized crop mix. This happens because the application<br />

<strong>of</strong> chemical fertilizer permits farmer to alter the relationship between soil <strong>and</strong> crop<br />

suitability.<br />

In examining the role <strong>of</strong> socio-economic factors on the levels <strong>of</strong> diversification,<br />

Minot et al. (2006) indicated that increase in diversity is positively related with age,<br />

education, <strong>and</strong> larger household. But, no significant relationship was noted between farm<br />

size <strong>and</strong> diversity in the cropping pattern. Both, farm size <strong>and</strong> irrigation were negatively<br />


;()rreiated with diversification. In terms <strong>of</strong> labour use <strong>and</strong> its availability, it was expected<br />

rhat substitution <strong>of</strong> capital for labour would promote specialisation <strong>and</strong> result in scale<br />

tconomies. Conversely, when production is labour intensive, farm tends to be smaller<br />

<strong>and</strong> m()re diversified. In this context, Zimmerer (1991) argues that shortage <strong>of</strong> labour in<br />

ihe labour-intensive crops results in low pr<strong>of</strong>it by increasing diversification <strong>and</strong> hence it<br />

restricts diversification towards such crops. Additionally, seasonality in labour<br />

requirement results in looking for other jobs <strong>and</strong> it increases dependence on hired labour<br />

for crop production. In such conditions, farmers prefer to specialize in one crop.<br />

The role <strong>of</strong> market size on explaining specialisation or diversification was first<br />

investigated by Emran <strong>and</strong> Shilpi (2007). They provided an empirical evidence <strong>of</strong> nonlinearity<br />

in the relationship between crop specialisation <strong>and</strong> the extent <strong>of</strong> market size. The<br />

e~dence<br />

indicates existence <strong>of</strong> a monotonically increasing relationship between the<br />

degree <strong>of</strong> crop diversification among the households in a village <strong>and</strong> the extent <strong>of</strong> the<br />

relevant urban market. They showed evidence <strong>of</strong> a 'U' shaped pattern in the stages <strong>of</strong><br />

agricultural specialisation as it related to the extent <strong>of</strong> the market. The semi-parametric<br />

instrumental variable estimates explain that the villages initially diversify the crop<br />

p


2.1.3 <strong>Diversification</strong> represented as Share <strong>of</strong> High Value <strong>Crops</strong><br />

In literature, the term diversification is also connoted with higher allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong><br />

in favour <strong>of</strong> high value crops. The major issue here is the lack <strong>of</strong> any definite definition<br />

<strong>of</strong> the index <strong>of</strong> proportion <strong>of</strong> high value crops. Different measures have been used by<br />

many studies, but interestingly some <strong>of</strong> them have identical views on the certain factors<br />

in driving diversification towards high value crops in India.<br />

The role <strong>of</strong> farm size in diversification towards high value crops has received<br />

widespread attention. It is because in many developing countries, including India, small<br />

farmers dominate the l<strong>and</strong>holdings. In the context <strong>of</strong> India, as the size <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong>holding <strong>and</strong><br />

farm size has been shrinking over a period <strong>of</strong> time, it is argued that it may bring natural<br />

constraints for diversification. Lack <strong>of</strong> scale economies <strong>and</strong> poor resource base may<br />

retard diversification. Besides, small farmers lack bargaining power <strong>and</strong> face high risk.<br />

They are over-dependent on their l<strong>and</strong> for their subsistence <strong>and</strong> that could playa critical<br />

role in diversifYing towards high value crops. In addition to farm size, market<br />

unavailability or small size <strong>of</strong> markets, lack <strong>of</strong> proper l<strong>and</strong> rights, lack <strong>of</strong> irrigation<br />

infrastructure <strong>and</strong> lack <strong>of</strong> investment <strong>and</strong> institutions could be additional constraints in<br />

diversification towards high value crops (Pingali, 2004, Joshi, 2005, Barghouti et aI.,<br />

2004, Mruthyunjaya <strong>and</strong> Chauhan, 2003, Ch<strong>and</strong>, 1996, Pingali, 1997; Alagh <strong>and</strong> Alagh,<br />

2003 <strong>and</strong> Agarwal, 2004).<br />

Non-availability <strong>of</strong> inputs including labour <strong>and</strong> seeds has been indicated as strong<br />

emerging constraint in diversification. Some studies have located an inverse relation<br />

between farm size <strong>and</strong> diversification towards high value crops (Ch<strong>and</strong>, 1996, Ch<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

Chauhan, 2(02). This was mainly because <strong>of</strong> the per unit decline in pr<strong>of</strong>it with increase<br />

in farm size. The pr<strong>of</strong>it declines due to application <strong>of</strong> limited resources including labour<br />

(Saleth, 1996, Ch<strong>and</strong>, 1996 <strong>and</strong> Haque, 1996). The role <strong>of</strong> farm size as a constraint on<br />

diversification towards high value crops was highlighted by Ch<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Chauhan (2002).<br />

They used a dynamic measure <strong>of</strong> diversification in production choices. In their analysis,<br />

they have showed that in India, availability <strong>of</strong> irrigation, network <strong>of</strong> roads <strong>and</strong> markets<br />

45


promote diversification in a very significant way whereas, small size <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong>holding act<br />

as a strong constraint.<br />

Several other studies on this issue have not found any bias against pro-small farmer<br />

in diversification towards high value crops. This could be attributed to difference in the<br />

definition or index <strong>of</strong> diversification used. Joshi (2005) used an index <strong>of</strong> gross value <strong>of</strong><br />

horticultural crops as a proxy to diversification towards high value crops in order to<br />

analyse the factors determining diversification in four broad regions in India. . The study<br />

noted a negative <strong>and</strong> significant relation between farm size, irrigation <strong>and</strong> diversification.<br />

This means that fann size <strong>and</strong> irrigation do not act as a constraint to diversification<br />

towards high value crops in India. This is in contrast to the argument put forth by Pingali<br />

(2004), who argued that lack <strong>of</strong> rainfall <strong>and</strong> irrigation facilities act as constraint for<br />

diversification.<br />

Ch<strong>and</strong> (I996) noted an inverse relation between farm size <strong>and</strong> diversification,<br />

where he defmed diversification as an index <strong>of</strong> high proportion <strong>of</strong> vegetables in area<br />

under cultivation. According to the study, it is irrigation <strong>and</strong> market access in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

distance that increase fanner's diversification towards vegetable crops. Agarwal (2004)<br />

illustrated that diversification in favour <strong>of</strong> high paid crops can be enhanced by increasing<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>it <strong>and</strong> reducing risk. But the effect is more visible in highly favourable regions as<br />

compared to unfavourable regions.<br />

Almost similar results were established by Rao et aL (2004), who used different<br />

indicators to analyse diversification towards high value crops (HVCs). Their prime aim<br />

was to examine the role <strong>of</strong> urbanization in diversification in India. Separating districts on<br />

the basis <strong>of</strong> their share <strong>of</strong> HVCs, the study established that absence <strong>of</strong> access to<br />

technology, inadequate infrastructure <strong>and</strong> lack <strong>of</strong> policy support are responsible for low<br />

diversification. Urban districts have a higher share <strong>of</strong> HVCs as compared to the urban<br />

areas surrounded <strong>and</strong> other districts. This is because urban surrounded districts with<br />

better road network have been able to diversify faster due to the dem<strong>and</strong> for HVCs in<br />

these centers. More importantly, the study also confirmed the results <strong>of</strong> other studies that<br />

small fanns were able to diversify more towards HVCs. Technological, agro-climatic,<br />

46


agrarian structure, <strong>and</strong> infrastructure variables like roads, markets <strong>and</strong> veterinary facilities<br />

are additional factors that have significantly influenced diversification towards HVCs in<br />

India.<br />

Birthal et aI, (2007), using proportion <strong>of</strong> area under fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetable as an index<br />

<strong>of</strong> diversification, established that diversification exhibits a pro smallholder rather than a<br />

pro large-holder bias. The smallholders, however, playa proportionally larger role in the<br />

production <strong>of</strong> vegetables than in the cultivation <strong>of</strong> fruits. The explanation for this<br />

outcome is that small farmers in India are endowed with high amount <strong>of</strong> labour which is<br />

reflected in greater family size. As vegetable crops are more labour intensive, labour<br />

endowment <strong>of</strong> small farmers induce them to diversify towards vegetables. Cultivation <strong>of</strong><br />

fruits is more capital intensive; this could potentially explain the choice <strong>of</strong> production <strong>of</strong><br />

the small-holders in India, who are generally poor. They do not find evidence that a<br />

greater share <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> is allocated by either the small or the medium holders to fruits or<br />

vegetables. Indeed, the share allocated to vegetables is significantly higher only if the<br />

family size is bigger.<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> could be an accumulative or survival strategy. While treating<br />

diversification as a desperate strategy, risk is taken as a significant factor. The riskaversion<br />

is expected to have an important influence on farmer behaviour, e.g. least riskaverse<br />

farmers would hold portfolios with high-risk investment, which generate higher<br />

average pr<strong>of</strong>its per unit <strong>of</strong> wealth as risky assets generate higher returns (Rosenzweig <strong>and</strong><br />

Binswanger, 1993). Such behaviour may be revealed by higher level <strong>of</strong> diversification<br />

towards high value crops. Economic theory suggests that a risk neutral producer allocates<br />

labour such that expected marginal returns are equalized (Heady, 1952). If one crop<br />

carries a greater marginal return, more labour will be supplied to that opportunity. A riskaverse<br />

farmer perceives a greater variance in earnings in one crop compared to another<br />

<strong>and</strong> will devote more time to less risky alternative <strong>and</strong> accept lower earnings (Mishra <strong>and</strong><br />

Goodwin, 1997). In other words, risk can be an important constraint for increasing<br />

diversification towards high value crops.<br />

47


Risk is important because as farmers allocate a large share <strong>of</strong> labour <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> to<br />

production <strong>of</strong> commercial crops, they become vulnerable to the fluctuations in the price<br />

<strong>of</strong> both food <strong>and</strong> commercial crops. In other words, by diversification, household<br />

dependency on market for food increases, which may be risky, if the prices <strong>of</strong> the<br />

commercial <strong>and</strong> food crops are highly variable. Based on this logic, it is expected that<br />

households with large family size will not diversify much towards high value commercial<br />

crops. Another explanation for subsistence production is the desire to avoid high<br />

transaction costs in selling crops <strong>and</strong> buying food. Transaction costs reduce the selling<br />

price <strong>of</strong> food crops <strong>and</strong> raise the buying price <strong>of</strong> food crops. The greater the transaction<br />

costs, including the cost <strong>of</strong> transportation to or from the market, it is more likely that<br />

those rura1 households will be subsistence farmers. <strong>Diversification</strong> towards high value<br />

commercial crops is also likely to be greater for rura1 households with good market<br />

access, as against remote <strong>and</strong> sparsely populated areas (Minot et al. 20(6).<br />

Until early 1990s, one <strong>of</strong> the most common critiques on diversification was that<br />

switching from food production to cash crop production may adversely affect food<br />

security <strong>and</strong> nutrition. This view was disputed by Braun (1995), who cited a series <strong>of</strong><br />

studies based on household surveys that compared income, food intake, <strong>and</strong> nutritional<br />

status <strong>of</strong> farm households. The study i11ustrated that farmers involved in cash crop<br />

production were generally better <strong>of</strong>f on various dimensions than similar households that<br />

were more subsistence oriented. Another major detenninant diversification is the<br />

opportunity cost <strong>of</strong> family labour <strong>and</strong> level <strong>of</strong> market dem<strong>and</strong> for food <strong>and</strong> other high<br />

value crops (Pingali <strong>and</strong> Rosegrant, 1995). In addition, Reardon et al. (1992) showed that<br />

households' capacity to cope with the drought shocks were strongly associated with the<br />

extent <strong>of</strong> their diversification patterns.<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> towards high value crops is also explained on the basis <strong>of</strong> the<br />

capacity <strong>of</strong>farmers to involve in non-farm income activity. It can affect diversification in<br />

both positive <strong>and</strong> negative manner. It is argued that risk management helps in explaining<br />

diversification away from crop production toward non-farm activities such as wage<br />

labour <strong>and</strong> non-farm enterprises (Evans <strong>and</strong> Nau, 1991). Following conventional<br />

argument, increased dem<strong>and</strong> associated with rising non-farm income leads to<br />

I<br />

48


diversification, <strong>and</strong> the growth <strong>of</strong> jobs in non-fann sector (Mellor, 1976). As the rural<br />

households are increasingly engaged in the non-farm activities, the proportion <strong>of</strong> nonfarm<br />

income in total income increases <strong>and</strong> may result in the poor productivity <strong>of</strong> the<br />

crops. Hence, there may be a trade <strong>of</strong>f between the non-farm income activity<br />

participation <strong>and</strong> better technology adoption <strong>and</strong> diversification towards high value crop.<br />

In one <strong>of</strong> the studies Evans <strong>and</strong> Ngau (1991), explained a positive correlation between<br />

income diversification, <strong>and</strong> crop production decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers that resulted in<br />

increased diversification towards high value crops <strong>and</strong> commercialization. Barrett <strong>and</strong><br />

Reardon et al (2000) examined the role <strong>of</strong> heterogeneity <strong>and</strong> incentives due to several<br />

factors in the income strategies by the farmers <strong>and</strong> its impact on their income. The study<br />

assessed the role <strong>of</strong> livelihood diversification on the pattern <strong>of</strong> asset allocation <strong>and</strong><br />

income sourcing among rural population by using data at farm level from three countries.<br />

The study found that the households having no access to non-fann activities or sufficient<br />

productive non-labour assets i.e., l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> livestock devoted themselves entirely to onfarm<br />

agricultural production. They rely on a low return strategy by complete dependence<br />

on agriculture <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong>ten [md themselves caught in a dynamic poverty trap. This also<br />

explains their apathy for diversification towards high value crops.<br />

In sum, majority <strong>of</strong> the studies emphasized primarily on non-economic factors.<br />

Additionally, while dealing with economic factors, most <strong>of</strong> them concentrated on ex post<br />

outcomes as a guiding principle <strong>of</strong> diversification decisions by farmers. However, it may<br />

be argued that while taking diversification decision, farmers remain ignorant about the<br />

actual economic outcome <strong>of</strong> their behaviour. But, their economic reasoning is influenced<br />

by their past experience in the production <strong>of</strong> crop, which is considered ex ante. Also, as<br />

diversification decision changes over a period <strong>of</strong> time from low value to high value crop<br />

<strong>and</strong> vice versa, there arises a need to consider the relative role <strong>of</strong> economic <strong>and</strong> noneconomic<br />

factors in diversification decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers.<br />

2.2 Risk, Uncertainty <strong>and</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> Decisions<br />

Risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty are vital aspects in the decision making <strong>of</strong> farmers with regard<br />

1 0 diversification. There can be three definitions <strong>of</strong> risk, namely, risk as the chance <strong>of</strong> a<br />

49


ad outcome, risk as the variability <strong>of</strong> outcomes <strong>and</strong> risk as uncertainty <strong>of</strong> outcomes<br />

(Hardaker, 2000). In classical literature, the basic difference between risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty<br />

is that risk can be quantified, whereas uncertainty cannot be (Knight, 1921). Analysis <strong>of</strong><br />

risk is objective in nature whereas analysis <strong>of</strong> uncertainty is subjective in nature.<br />

The studies on risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty commenced with the emergence <strong>of</strong> Expected<br />

Utility (EU) approach. Von Neumann <strong>and</strong> Morgenstem (1944) were the major<br />

contributors to a larger body <strong>of</strong> work that provided normative justification for the use <strong>of</strong><br />

EU by rational decision makers. The EU model is based on a set <strong>of</strong> axioms, which<br />

impose intuitively possible restrictions on preferences. It states that a decision maker<br />

chooses between risky or uncertain prospects by comparing their expected utility values.<br />

The shape <strong>of</strong> the utility function characterizes a decision maker's risk attitude. A riskaverse<br />

individual or fanner will prefer certainty in income, a risk-neutral individual will<br />

be indifferent between the two <strong>and</strong> a risk-taker will prefer to gamble. The intuitive way <strong>of</strong><br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing risk aversion comes from the behaviour that a possible loss <strong>of</strong> a given size<br />

is more important than a gain <strong>of</strong> the same size. In the study <strong>of</strong> economic choices in risky<br />

situations, it is <strong>of</strong>ten convenient to have a quantitative measure <strong>of</strong> risk aversion. The most<br />

commonly used measure <strong>of</strong> risk aversion was originally developed by Pratt (1964), but<br />

cften called as the Arrow-Pratt measure <strong>of</strong> 'absolute risk aversion'. Later, Arrow (1971)<br />

provided another measure <strong>of</strong> risk-aversion, which is called as 'relative risk aversion'.<br />

Arrow assumed that a person would be more willing to accept risk as his income<br />

increased with increasing wealth.<br />

However, in spite <strong>of</strong> its wider use, EU model was criticized as a growing number <strong>of</strong><br />

empirical observations reported violation <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> its axiomatic foundations <strong>and</strong> a<br />

divergence <strong>of</strong> observed decisions from what was predicted by the EU models. EU models<br />

were found inadequate to account for the impacts <strong>of</strong> anxieties <strong>and</strong> worry associated with<br />

r<strong>and</strong>om outcomes or choices, or the effort <strong>and</strong> experience needed for optimal selection<br />

(Buschena <strong>and</strong> Zilberman, 1994). Additionally, EU models could not include elements<br />

()ther than income in the utility function. Roumasset (1976), criticized the EU models <strong>and</strong><br />

mean variance analysis for studying the decision making <strong>of</strong> farmers, especially in the<br />

50


context <strong>of</strong> developing countries as it paid no attention to the cost <strong>of</strong> gathering <strong>and</strong><br />

processing information. _<br />

The studies pertaining to downside risks also criticised EU based models. Downside<br />

risk measures are based on the intuition that most decision makers including fanners give<br />

more weight to negative deviations. There was growing empirical evidence suggesting<br />

that most farmers exhibited decreasing absolute risk aversion (decreasing absolute risk<br />

aversion (DARA» (Binswanger, 1981), which implied that fanners were averse to<br />

"downside risk". Roy (1952) was the pioneer in putting downside risks in perspective.<br />

The concept was further developed by Markowitz (\959), who developed the concept for<br />

portfolio management. He developed his argument on the premise that investors were<br />

interested in minimizing downside risk for two reasons: (I) only down side risk or<br />

Safety-First is relevant to them <strong>and</strong> (2) security distributions may not be nonnally<br />

distributed. The most commonly used downside risk measures are semi-variance, lower<br />

partial moments <strong>and</strong> Value at Risk (VaR) (Yilma, 2(05).<br />

The Expected utility maximization models were described as a "full optimality<br />

model" that excluded the costs <strong>of</strong> making decision. The full optimality models do not<br />

take into account the limited capacities <strong>of</strong> individual decision makers for imagination <strong>and</strong><br />

computation. Roumasset (\ 976) argues that when costs <strong>of</strong> obtaining <strong>and</strong> processing<br />

information are substantial, it is not necessarily rational for an individual to act<br />

consistently with his underlying preferences. He defines risk as the probability that the<br />

stochastic variable, <strong>of</strong>ten net income, will take on a value less than some critical<br />

minimum or disaster level. He explained three Safety-First models:<br />

I. Safety principle involves minimization <strong>of</strong> the probability <strong>of</strong> some objective<br />

function, usually pr<strong>of</strong>its, falling below a specified disaster level. This can be<br />

expressed as: min a=. Pr (x


exogenously specified crucial probability. This can be expressed as: max E(I[)<br />

. subject to a ~Pr(Jt < d) where expected pr<strong>of</strong>it E(Jt) is the objective function, d is the<br />

exogenously determined disaster level <strong>and</strong> a is the exogenously specified<br />

probability limit.<br />

3. Safety-Fixed principle maximizes the minimum return, which can be attained with a<br />

fIXed confidence level. That is: max d subject to a=. Pr(Jt


<strong>and</strong> figure out what will be the possible outcomes. It is the enjoyment or satisfaction<br />

provided by these outcomes that guide the choice <strong>of</strong> the decision-maker. Shackle (1958)<br />

brought the concept <strong>of</strong> potential surprise here. According to him, between a feeling <strong>of</strong><br />

certainty that a given event will happen <strong>and</strong> a feeling <strong>of</strong> certainty that it will not, there<br />

seems to be a continuous range <strong>of</strong> different levels at which degree <strong>of</strong> belief can st<strong>and</strong>.<br />

The higher the degree <strong>of</strong> belief, higher is the potential surprise. Surprise means that the<br />

individual's structure <strong>of</strong> expectations either contains a misjudgement or has been<br />

incomplete. The real incentive for choosing an action is the enjoyment <strong>of</strong> anticipating a<br />

high level <strong>of</strong> success. The intensity <strong>of</strong> enjoyment is a decreasing function <strong>of</strong> the degree <strong>of</strong><br />

potential surprise <strong>and</strong> increasing function <strong>of</strong> the outcome. The combination <strong>of</strong> potential<br />

surprise <strong>and</strong> the attention-arresting power produces what Shackle calls focus-values.<br />

These will be the best (focus-gain) <strong>and</strong> the worst (focus-loss) outcomes that concern the<br />

decision maker. Comparing these focus-values, farmer would assess the attractiveness <strong>of</strong><br />

his course <strong>of</strong> action in a comparison with others <strong>and</strong> take the decision. But, Shackle<br />

(1949) restricts from carrying out any empirical exercise on the concepts introduced by<br />

him. The question is how these expectations are formed? In this line <strong>of</strong> thought, Williams<br />

(1951) examines the nature <strong>of</strong> price expectations as a response to uncertainty. The moot<br />

question addressed was that whether farmers formed expectations <strong>of</strong> all or some crops<br />

together or they formed price expectation <strong>of</strong> each crop separately. William (I9S1)<br />

obtained prices that farmers expected from the production <strong>of</strong> the selected crops <strong>and</strong><br />

grouped the farmers on the basis <strong>of</strong> different ranges <strong>of</strong> price expectations. The study<br />

indicated that farmers did formulate expectations for each crop separately <strong>and</strong> for all<br />

crops together.<br />

There have been a few empirical attempts to examme the role <strong>of</strong> risk <strong>and</strong><br />

uncertainty on diversification decision <strong>of</strong> farmers. Prominent among these are<br />

Shahabuddin et al. (1986), who tried to fmd the extent to which diversification by farmers<br />

were caused by risk attitude. They incorporated Roy's Safety-First principle into the<br />

resource allocation models where the risk coefficient was 'I' = [(d-u,)/cr,J. The relative<br />

magnitude <strong>of</strong> the variables'd' <strong>and</strong> 'Ur'determines whether the farm family is forced to<br />

gamble (d>u,.) or allowed to trade expected return for reduced risk (d


crop portfolio. They attempted to explain the intra-household variations in risk<br />

coefficients in terms <strong>of</strong> variations in the income earning potential <strong>and</strong> subsistence needs<br />

<strong>of</strong> the farm families. The study found a sigoificant relation between farm size (-), family<br />

size (+), otT-farm activities (-) <strong>and</strong> risk aversion.<br />

In order to account for the uncertainty in representing farmer's diversification<br />

decision, Boussard <strong>and</strong> Petit (1967) used the concept <strong>of</strong> possibility <strong>of</strong> ruin, a concept<br />

closely related to Shackle's focus <strong>of</strong> loss. They integrated this into the linear<br />

programming production decision model by incorporating constraint <strong>of</strong> crop choice on<br />

the basis <strong>of</strong> working capital requirements, access to credit, minimum permitted loss <strong>and</strong><br />

technical constraints in four types <strong>of</strong> cropping patterns. The study illustrates that the<br />

model with security <strong>and</strong> credit constraints is more predictive as compared to model only<br />

with either technical constraint or security constraint. They have taken into account yield<br />

<strong>and</strong> price uncertainties in explaining diversification decisions <strong>of</strong> the farmer but<br />

overlooked other types <strong>of</strong> uncertainty like labour requirements <strong>and</strong> timeliness <strong>of</strong><br />

operations, which are equally important. Binswanger (1981) assessed the risk attitudes <strong>of</strong><br />

rural households in semi-arid tropics <strong>of</strong> India <strong>and</strong> asserted that higher level <strong>of</strong> risk lead to<br />

under-investment in agriculture relative to the expected pr<strong>of</strong>it maximizing levels.<br />

According to the study, it is the progressive farmers that are slightly less risk averse than<br />

average farmers at high pay-otT levels <strong>and</strong> there is a negative relationship between risk<br />

aversion <strong>and</strong> size <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong>holding. It was noted that farmers in areas which had the worst<br />

history <strong>of</strong> droughts, were more risk averse than their counterparts in other areas.<br />

Kunreuther <strong>and</strong> Wright (1979), showed that cash crop are in-fact the risky choice<br />

for a subsistence farmer. A farmer who buys his food must consider the yield variance <strong>of</strong><br />

the cash crop as well as the price variance <strong>of</strong> both the crops. But, for the farmer who<br />

grows or consumes his own crop, only yield variance is relevant. The study tried to build<br />

a model based on the assumption <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it-maximizing behaviour <strong>of</strong> farmers with<br />

constraint due to some minimum requirements (consumption) critical for survival <strong>of</strong><br />

farmers. They found that the farmers following Safety-First strategy might misallocate<br />

their resources by allocating substantial portion <strong>of</strong> their l<strong>and</strong> with a food crop with a<br />

I01er expected return than the cash crop. This misallocation arises from the institutional<br />

54


arrangements <strong>of</strong> agricultural sector like farm size, tenancy or technical inefficiency.<br />

According to them, to achieve a more efficient allocation <strong>of</strong> resources. two choices are<br />

open: either to reduce the Safety-First farmers to risk-takers or give them enough security<br />

so that they will focus more on the relative expected returns from their crops <strong>and</strong> less on<br />

their variance.<br />

The consumption requirements depict the partial requirement <strong>of</strong> farmers <strong>and</strong> it does<br />

not capture their overall concern. It excludes farmers' access to credit <strong>and</strong> assets at their<br />

disposal. Since the overall resources <strong>and</strong> access to resources differs from farmer to<br />

farmer, the level <strong>of</strong> risk taken by them also differs. Accounting for this, Ortiz (1979)<br />

reviewed how uncertainty affects the process <strong>of</strong> decision, the ability to formulate<br />

prospects <strong>of</strong> gain or loss, as well as value <strong>of</strong> the lowest permissible return I I. He explained<br />

that risky incomes were responsible for the subsistence-first strategy by farmers. The<br />

uncertainty in availability <strong>of</strong> inputs inhibits the formulation <strong>of</strong> prospects <strong>and</strong> any a priori<br />

planning <strong>of</strong> food production. Once basic subsistence requirements are insured, peasants<br />

plant one <strong>of</strong> the local cash crops even when the chances were that the return would barely<br />

cover costs.<br />

In sum, expectations <strong>and</strong> risk are the major aspects <strong>of</strong> this group <strong>of</strong> studies.<br />

However, there are very few empirical studies on these aspects probably due to<br />

measurement <strong>and</strong> other challenges. At the farm level, the concept <strong>of</strong> expectation is<br />

generally used in terms <strong>of</strong> a response to uncertainty involved in the production process.<br />

There are several ways in which the information regarding expectation is obtained, which<br />

used probability or possibility analyses in measuring such expectations. Since, probability<br />

is much <strong>of</strong> a utopian concept, possibility only is considered as relevant. But, there is<br />

hardly any study on how such expectations are formed, <strong>and</strong> what factors influence<br />

expectations <strong>of</strong> farmers. Additionally, farmers build expectations about different<br />

economic outcomes including price, yield <strong>and</strong> income. There is a need to examine the<br />

11 Permissible loss given by Boussard as [Lv ~ E (m~e;) X; • (em + F m)] where m; is Ihe unitary gross<br />

receipts on the ith activity at tbe focus gain level, 'c' is the corresponding current expenses, C is the<br />

farmer's vital consumption, F is all thp compulsory payments not included in 'e' <strong>and</strong> 'j' is the number <strong>of</strong><br />

;lcti~ties<br />

55


extent to which different expectation about economic outcome helps m guiding<br />

diversification decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers.<br />

There are several studies dealing with risk that consider crop-specific risk in guiding<br />

diversification decisions. But, in the event <strong>of</strong> dominance <strong>of</strong> one crop in the income<br />

generating activity at the farm level, aggregate risk on income <strong>and</strong> production is more<br />

vital in guiding the decision <strong>of</strong> farmers. It is vital to capture such decisions by using the<br />

fann level data regarding price, yield <strong>and</strong> cost to compute the risk typology <strong>and</strong> its<br />

influence on diversification decisions.<br />

2.3. Role <strong>of</strong> Changing Typology <strong>of</strong> Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> on<br />

Agricultural Growth<br />

Decomposition models are pivotal for examining the relevance <strong>of</strong> changing<br />

allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> on income growth. lbrough decomposition model, one can gauge the<br />

role <strong>of</strong> various components <strong>of</strong> growth for any particular crop as well as for a region as a<br />

whole. It is important to highlight that most work on decomposition was on improving<br />

the methodology in explaining the growth rate in income <strong>of</strong> crop <strong>and</strong> region. There were<br />

several attempts before 1965 to explain agricultural growth, but only area <strong>and</strong> yield were<br />

considered as components <strong>of</strong> growth. Incorporation <strong>of</strong> another component, diversification<br />

or changing cropping pattern, was an important development in the analyses <strong>of</strong><br />

agricultural growth. Minhas <strong>and</strong> Vaidyanathan (\965) were the first to add the<br />

component <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern <strong>and</strong> a residual component representing interaction<br />

between yields <strong>and</strong> cropping pattern, in order to explain the agricultural growth. The<br />

observed change in aggregate output was decomposed into four-component elements i.e.,<br />

the contribution <strong>of</strong> (i) changes in area, (ii) changes in per acre yields, (iii) changes in<br />

cropping pattern, <strong>and</strong> (iv) the interaction <strong>of</strong> the latter two elements. Here, cropping<br />

pattern is synonymous to reallocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> among crops <strong>of</strong> different values. The<br />

positive interaction between yield <strong>and</strong> cropping pattern would mean the diversion <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong><br />

towards the crops whose yields are higher. By using a district level analysis, Minhas <strong>and</strong><br />

Vaidyanathan (1965) found that role <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern was <strong>of</strong> less significance with the<br />

exception <strong>of</strong> few states like Punjab, Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong> etc. Later Minhas (1966) gave a<br />

56


seven-component version that added new interaction terms between area, croppmg<br />

pattern <strong>and</strong> yields. A positive area~ropping pattern interaction indicated an increase in<br />

gross crop area in favour <strong>of</strong> high productivity crops. However, by following the new<br />

seven~mponent analysis, the study could not find any significant change in the results<br />

as compared to results <strong>of</strong> the four components model. It was suggested that the seven<br />

component model should be used only if the role <strong>of</strong> interaction effect in the four<br />

component model is significantly high.<br />

Minhas model was criticized by Narula <strong>and</strong> VidyaSagar (1973) for having given<br />

weights for current year <strong>and</strong> base year to the changes in yield <strong>and</strong> area, respectively.<br />

They argued that the postulation created biases as it always gave a preferential treatment<br />

to the changes in yield by giving a weight for current year area <strong>and</strong> to changes in area by<br />

giving weight for base year yield specifically in a situation where both area <strong>and</strong> yield<br />

rates varied overtime. The authors suggested that these biases <strong>of</strong> weights could be<br />

reduced by giving average weights i.e., to take current <strong>and</strong> base years average <strong>of</strong> area <strong>and</strong><br />

yields as weight to the change in yield <strong>and</strong> change in area respectively.<br />

incorporation <strong>of</strong> the price variable in the decomposition model was done for the<br />

first time by VidyaSagar (·1977) who decomposed the change in the value <strong>of</strong> gross<br />

agricultural output into gross components including area, productivity, price <strong>and</strong> their<br />

interactions. The analysis proceeds mainly in terms <strong>of</strong> productivity, which refers to the<br />

value <strong>of</strong> agricultural output per hectare at the current price structure. Price structure is<br />

defined as "the set <strong>of</strong> current year prices such that the overall average price <strong>of</strong><br />

agricultural crops remains at a constant level, while at the same time it incorporates the<br />

movements in prices relative to each other". Here, the price component measures the<br />

effect <strong>of</strong> inflation on the growth in the value <strong>of</strong> output. His analysis in Rajasthan<br />

illustrates that despite incorporating price variable, the change in the income was still<br />

influenced more by productivity followed by the area expansion. The role <strong>of</strong> price was<br />

very less <strong>and</strong> that <strong>of</strong> a cropping pattern mix was negative.<br />

Another component <strong>of</strong> decomposition analysis was the in:roduction <strong>of</strong> crop<br />

structural component i.e. the locational shift by Narain (1976). According to him, a<br />

57


positive locational component implies a shift in crop locations from low productivity<br />

regions to high productivity regions. A positive interaction will similarly show a shift in<br />

favour <strong>of</strong>locations with higher growth in crop yields. The study indicates that in India the<br />

real gain in productivity resulting from locational shifts is rather small, thus reflecting on<br />

the limited role-play <strong>of</strong> the market forces in bringing about inter-regional specialisation in<br />

the production <strong>of</strong> crops. Narain (1976) included the cropping pattern as a component <strong>of</strong><br />

yield growth but he did not include the role <strong>of</strong> changing structure <strong>of</strong> prices in the crops<br />

movements. The same method was modified <strong>and</strong> used by Ranade (1980) who<br />

investigated the role <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern, fertilizer <strong>and</strong> irrigation by using district level<br />

data spread over 16 states <strong>and</strong> 54 agro-c1imatic zones. The difference is that Narain<br />

(1976) considers the base year yield <strong>and</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> different crops while Ranade (1980)<br />

uses an index all-India average yields <strong>and</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> different crops. He used tabulation,<br />

correlation <strong>and</strong> regression model to run yield regression on fertilizer, irrigation <strong>and</strong><br />

cropping pattern index. The study established significant <strong>and</strong> positive impact <strong>of</strong> cropping<br />

pattern index on the agriculturaI productivity.<br />

Along with additive schemes, some <strong>of</strong> the studies dealing with decomposition <strong>of</strong><br />

agricuituraI growth have employed multiplicative schemes. Unlike additive schemes,<br />

which decompose absolute increase <strong>and</strong> hence give linear growth rate <strong>of</strong> output, the<br />

multiplicative scheme decomposes compound rate <strong>of</strong> growth. Parikh (1966) expresses the<br />

index number <strong>of</strong> output as a multiple respectively <strong>of</strong> the index numbers <strong>of</strong> area, change in<br />

cropping pattern <strong>and</strong> change in crop yields. By fitting exponential time-trend to each<br />

series <strong>of</strong> index numbers, he gets multiplicative scheme for growth. In order to estimate<br />

the contribution <strong>of</strong> each component, two indices were constructed - index number <strong>of</strong><br />

agriCUltural production for constant crop pattern <strong>and</strong> index number <strong>of</strong> changes in crop<br />

pattern. In the first instance, a series <strong>of</strong> area under crops keeping crop pattern constant at<br />

base year level were evolved. This was done by reallocating the gross cropped area to<br />

individual crops on the basis <strong>of</strong> their proportion in the base year. Secondly, the area under<br />

individual crops was multiplied by their respective yield per acre to obtain the production<br />

<strong>of</strong> individual crops, which when added, gave aggregate production keeping out the effects<br />

<strong>of</strong> changes in crop pattern. This gave two series- (i) total production which includes the<br />

58


influence <strong>of</strong> changes in crop pattern, <strong>and</strong> (ii) total production which does not include the<br />

influence <strong>of</strong> crop pattern change. The second series is an index <strong>of</strong> production for constant<br />

crop pattern. The growth rate <strong>of</strong> each <strong>of</strong> these components was obtained by fitting the<br />

semi-log trend.<br />

Later Minhas (1966) gave his multiplicative scheme as an improvement over<br />

Parikh's version. He extends the identity given by Parilch in order to measure the<br />

cropping pattern effect at base period yields <strong>and</strong> in the process introduces a residual<br />

component. The residual figure is the ratio <strong>of</strong> the product <strong>of</strong> any given period<br />

productivity <strong>and</strong> base period productivity to the product <strong>of</strong> the same period productivity<br />

obtained by changing the crop pattern <strong>and</strong> by growth in crop yields respectively. This is<br />

the same as the interaction between cropping pattern <strong>and</strong> yield components in the<br />

additive models.<br />

The major concern was that most <strong>of</strong> the studies had computed growth in output or<br />

productivity <strong>and</strong> its components by comparing the end points <strong>of</strong> the series. The use <strong>of</strong><br />

point-to-point method <strong>of</strong> measuring growth may lead to biased estimates <strong>of</strong> growth unless<br />

care is taken in selecting the points <strong>of</strong> comparison. Often three year time points are<br />

considered to adjust for the short run fluctuations arising from the vagaries <strong>of</strong> weather.<br />

But this may prove wrong in some cases <strong>and</strong> therefore great care is needed in selecting<br />

both the base year <strong>and</strong> the averages <strong>of</strong> years.<br />

Taking into account the problem related to the use <strong>of</strong> end point, Minot et al. (2006)<br />

used total derivative, instead <strong>of</strong> two different points for decomposing growth rate. The<br />

aim <strong>of</strong> the study was to find how much diversification was occurring in Vietnam <strong>and</strong> how<br />

much did it contribute to income growth. The study decomposes income growth into<br />

yield, area expansion, price changes, diversification into high value crops <strong>and</strong><br />

diversification into non-farm activities. It was found that poor farmers earned more by<br />

increasing crop yields, while richer household exp<strong>and</strong>ed the area under cultivation. The<br />

analysis indicated that diversification into higher value crop accounted for just 6 percent<br />

<strong>of</strong> the crop income growth. But, they conceded that there results were regional <strong>and</strong> time<br />

specific <strong>and</strong> the same might change across regions through different time periods.<br />

59


The same model was used by Joshi (2005) to find study the role <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern<br />

shift on income growth in the pre <strong>and</strong> post libernlization period across different regions in<br />

India. The study confirmed that sources <strong>of</strong> agricultural growth had changed dramatically<br />

over the last two decades in India. More importantly, it was found that the significance <strong>of</strong><br />

agricultural diversification is consistently increasing in explaining the growth in<br />

agriculture. But, there are stark differences in the relative importance <strong>of</strong> components <strong>of</strong><br />

growth across regions in India. Kurosaki (2003) empirically examined the long-term<br />

trends in agricultural production in West Punjab by using decomposition model. This<br />

study revealed that area increase accounted for 71 percent <strong>of</strong> the growth in an index <strong>of</strong><br />

agricultural output over 1903-1952, but during 1952-1992 the most important<br />

contributors were yield increases (53 percent) <strong>and</strong> diversification (7 percent). Finally, his<br />

analyses across districts indicated that road density <strong>and</strong> irrigation were associated with<br />

higher diversity during the first period, <strong>and</strong> these factors led to increased specialisation<br />

during second period.<br />

The studies dealing with diversification cover a wide range <strong>of</strong> aspects. Also there<br />

are diverse ways to interpret the significance <strong>of</strong> changing diversification. At the macro<br />

level, the major debate hovers around quantifying the significance <strong>of</strong> crop diversification<br />

in growth <strong>of</strong> output. As noted, there are several sub-components <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>and</strong><br />

each component affects growth in different ways. In terms <strong>of</strong> diversification towards high<br />

value crops, many researchers argue that a silent revolution <strong>of</strong> shift in cropping pattern<br />

towards high value crops is already under way (Joshi, 2006, Vyas, 1996, Ch<strong>and</strong>., 2005,<br />

Rao et al, 2004, Birthal et al,. 2007). But, how the process <strong>of</strong> diversification has affected<br />

the growth <strong>of</strong> output in India. <strong>Diversification</strong> may affect the growth through static <strong>and</strong><br />

dynamic effects. But most <strong>of</strong> the studies dealt with the static aspect <strong>of</strong> diversification,<br />

ignoring the dynamic aspect <strong>of</strong> the same. A positive static effect <strong>of</strong> diversification is a<br />

shift <strong>of</strong> crop structure in favour <strong>of</strong> high initial productivity crop. This does not capture the<br />

developments in the technology <strong>of</strong> crops that may change over time <strong>and</strong> may alter<br />

relative values <strong>of</strong> crops. In other words, over-time, the pr<strong>of</strong>itability or relative values <strong>of</strong><br />

crops does not remain constant <strong>and</strong> change in the productivity <strong>of</strong> crops may change the<br />

comparative advantage <strong>of</strong> the crops. Hence, it is also important to consider the dynamic<br />

60


effects <strong>of</strong> diversification that capture the concomitant movements <strong>of</strong> yield <strong>and</strong> cropping<br />

pattern change. The dynamic aspect <strong>of</strong> diver;;ification represents the impact <strong>of</strong> the joint<br />

movements on the diversification <strong>of</strong> crop pattern <strong>and</strong> that <strong>of</strong> technological change on<br />

overall output change. A positive dynamic effect <strong>of</strong> diversification will be a shift in crop<br />

structure in favour <strong>of</strong> those crops which show relatively higher growth in yield. Similarly,<br />

a negative dynamic effect implies over-time, cropping pattern shift in favour <strong>of</strong> those<br />

crops which could not experience higher growth in productivity. This results in growthdepressive<br />

impact <strong>of</strong> diversification on output generated in the agriCUltural sector. The<br />

question here is what is the role <strong>of</strong> diversification in the growth <strong>of</strong> output in Indian<br />

agricultural sector? Whether the process <strong>of</strong> changing cropping pattern has been growth<br />

inducive or depressive, <strong>and</strong> what factors have contributed to the nature <strong>and</strong> direction <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification in India?<br />

61


CHAPTER III<br />

DIVERSIFICATION AND CROP OUTPUT<br />

GROWTH IN INDIA: A STATE LEVEL ANALYSIS<br />

3.1 Introduction<br />

Agricultural development strategies in India have gone through four broad phases.<br />

These are: a) intensification <strong>of</strong> efforts in identified areas using traditional technology <strong>and</strong><br />

expansion <strong>of</strong> area during the pre-Green Revolution period; b) embarked on Green<br />

Revolution using modem inputs <strong>and</strong> high yielding varieties in irrigated areas during the<br />

late sixties <strong>and</strong> the seventies; c) then a period <strong>of</strong> greater focus on management <strong>of</strong> linkages<br />

<strong>and</strong> infrastructure, such as, marketing, trade <strong>and</strong> institution building; d) <strong>and</strong> fmally an era<br />

<strong>of</strong>liberalization <strong>and</strong> relaxation <strong>of</strong> controls during the nineties (Hazra, 2003).<br />

Several commendable achievements have been attained in the process <strong>of</strong><br />

development Food grains production increased four-fold since independence, from 51<br />

Million tonnes (MT) in 1950-51 to 203 MT in 2000-01. The Green, White, Yellow <strong>and</strong><br />

Blue Revolutions were l<strong>and</strong>marks that have been claimed <strong>and</strong> recognized the world over.<br />

India is now the largest producer <strong>of</strong> wheat, fruits, cashew nut, milk <strong>and</strong> tea in the world<br />

<strong>and</strong> second largest producer <strong>of</strong> vegetables. India is also the largest producer, consumer<br />

<strong>and</strong> exporter <strong>of</strong> spices in the world <strong>and</strong> the largest exporter <strong>of</strong> cashew. More importantly,<br />

the agricultural sector has left behind the era <strong>of</strong> food shortages <strong>and</strong> arrived at a stage <strong>of</strong><br />

self-sufficiency.<br />

There is, however, another side to this argument. First, the trend <strong>of</strong> decreasing<br />

output contribution by agriculture to Gross Domestic Product (GOP) <strong>and</strong> stagnant<br />

employment dependence on agriculture reflect the picture <strong>of</strong> an incomplete agricultural<br />

transformation. The higher economic <strong>and</strong> per capita growth in India over the previous<br />

few decades accompanied with drastic decline in agriculture share to GOP. Besides it, the<br />

,<br />

62


economy did not witness any perceptible movement <strong>of</strong> labour from agriculture to nonagricultural<br />

sector. Second, the perfonnance <strong>of</strong> agriculture sector in the recent years has<br />

been tardy as evidenced by the shatp deceleration in growth rate <strong>of</strong> agricultural output.<br />

The changing scenario <strong>of</strong> agriculture has forced the fanning community <strong>and</strong> policy<br />

makers to search for a more remunerative <strong>and</strong> viable production portfolios (Joshi, 2(05).<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> has turned out to be one such viable policy option to promote overall<br />

agricultural growth due to its potential to stabilize <strong>and</strong> raise farm income, decrease risk,<br />

increase employment opportunities <strong>and</strong> conserve natural resources in India (V yas 1996,<br />

Joshi 2005 <strong>and</strong> Ch<strong>and</strong> 2006).<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> has several components that include diversity in the cropping<br />

pattern, l<strong>and</strong> allocation to high value crops <strong>and</strong> change in cropping pattern among crops<br />

<strong>of</strong> different values. These components influence growth in different ways12. In the<br />

context <strong>of</strong> India, over a period <strong>of</strong> time, difference in the policies <strong>and</strong> external<br />

environment has led to a varied pattern <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>and</strong> related typology across<br />

states. Broadly, states can be distinguished on the basis <strong>of</strong> three patterns. In the first<br />

pattern, we have states, which followed the Green Revolution <strong>and</strong> adopted High Yield<br />

Varieties <strong>of</strong> few selected crops i.e. rice <strong>and</strong> wheat. These states shifted much <strong>of</strong> their area<br />

towards rice <strong>and</strong> wheat that led to specialisation. In the second pattern, we have states,<br />

which did not gain much from Green Revolution as they could not diversify much<br />

towards rice <strong>and</strong> wheat crops. However, these groups <strong>of</strong> states increased l<strong>and</strong> allocation<br />

towards other high value crops including non-food crops. In the third category, there are<br />

states, which neither diversified meaningfully towards rice <strong>and</strong> wheat nor towards nonfood<br />

crops.<br />

Investigating into the process <strong>of</strong> diversification requires initially an analysis <strong>of</strong> the<br />

typology which throws light on the number <strong>of</strong> crops, spread <strong>and</strong> concentration <strong>and</strong><br />

proportions <strong>of</strong> various crop groups. These have to be linked with the pattern <strong>of</strong> income<br />

<strong>and</strong> risk across states in India to view the macro-level picture. Besides this, the<br />

investigation into trends in growth <strong>of</strong> output <strong>and</strong> mapping the relative importance <strong>of</strong><br />

various components will help to underst<strong>and</strong> the pattern <strong>of</strong> growth in output <strong>and</strong> the role<br />

I~ These relationships are discussed in detail in Chapter one<br />

63


<strong>of</strong> diversification in the process. For the purpose, initially, vanous indices <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification were computed for the past three decades. Then, we linked these<br />

components <strong>of</strong> diversification with the pattern <strong>of</strong> income <strong>and</strong> risk. The subsequent<br />

section deals with the investigation <strong>of</strong> the trends in growth <strong>of</strong> output <strong>and</strong> gauges the<br />

relative importance <strong>of</strong> various components, including diversification in the pattern <strong>of</strong><br />

growth <strong>of</strong> output. The last section examines the factors influencing the nature <strong>and</strong><br />

direction <strong>of</strong> diversification in India.<br />

We confine our analysis to 30 crops (appendix 3.1) owing to non-availability <strong>of</strong><br />

data for a few minor crops for all states <strong>and</strong> for all the decades. These 30 crops account<br />

for an overwhelmingly large proportion <strong>of</strong> total cropped area <strong>and</strong> can be taken to be a fair<br />

approximation to overall picture. We have split the data into three decades 1970s, 1980s<br />

<strong>and</strong> 1990s. The reason for this split is that different policies marked these decades which<br />

influenced the typology <strong>of</strong> crop diversification in distinct ways. The period <strong>of</strong> I 970s was<br />

characterised by intensification <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> inputs <strong>and</strong> adoption <strong>of</strong> high yielding<br />

varieties <strong>of</strong> few selected crops. In the decade <strong>of</strong> 1980s, the emphasis <strong>of</strong> technology led<br />

development (Green Revolution <strong>and</strong> introduction <strong>of</strong> Technology Mission on Oilseeds)<br />

was furthered with increased ernphasis on infrastructure <strong>and</strong> markets. It was in the 1990s<br />

that liberalization <strong>of</strong> economy along with relaxation <strong>of</strong> controls took place. All the 17<br />

states have been categorised broadly into four distinct regions IJ. Each region is relatively<br />

homogenous in agro-ecological characteristics, <strong>and</strong> compositions <strong>of</strong> crop, although they<br />

differ in infrastructural <strong>and</strong> other socio-economic characteristics (Joshi et al. 2006)<br />

3.2 Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> in India<br />

3.2.1 Cropping Pattern Change in India<br />

The change in the typologies <strong>of</strong> diversification across states gets reflected at the<br />

economy level through different composition <strong>of</strong> crop contribution to gross cropped area<br />

Il Northern region includes Haryana, <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Punjab, J&K <strong>and</strong> Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong>. Eastern region<br />

comprises <strong>of</strong> Bihar, Assam, West Bengal <strong>and</strong> Orrisa. Western region consists <strong>of</strong> Rajasthan, Gujarat,<br />

idhya <strong>Pradesh</strong> <strong>and</strong> Maharashtra <strong>and</strong> Southern regioo includes AP, Kamataka, Kernla <strong>and</strong> Tamil Nadu<br />

64


<strong>and</strong> output generated in the agricultural sector. Despite existence <strong>of</strong> diverse a agroclimatic<br />

scenario, food grains dominate the crop sector, amongst which rice <strong>and</strong> wheat<br />

are the prominent crops (table 3.1). Over a period <strong>of</strong> time, the area under these crops has<br />

been steadily increasing <strong>and</strong> at present, these crops cover more than one-third <strong>of</strong> the gross<br />

cropped area (GCA) in India However, there has been a declining trend in the share <strong>of</strong><br />

area under other food grain crops. This is primarily due to reduction in area under coarse<br />

cereals <strong>and</strong> pulses, though, one can observe different patterns across states in India.<br />

Table 3.1: Contribution <strong>of</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> to Gross Cropped Area <strong>and</strong> Value <strong>of</strong> Output Produced in<br />

A \2ncu . It ura 1St ee or ID ' I n d' la<br />

TE TE TE TE TE TE TE<br />

1950-51 1960-61 1970-71 1980-81 1990-91 1999-00 2005-06<br />

Rice 23.20 22.80 22.72 23.28 23.76 24.03 22.11<br />

(17.1) (20.5) • (19·31 (19.9) (20.3) (18.2)<br />

Wheat 7.50 8.75 11.56 13.21 13.04 13.84 13.88<br />

(4.0) (4.7) (7.9) • (9.6) . (10.8) (11.6)<br />

Total 15.63 15.05 13.88 13.62 13.29 11.40 12.43<br />

Pulses (12.3) (12.4) (9.1) (6.9) (6.7) (4.10)<br />

Food grains 77.01 75.66 74.99 73.38 68.83 65.83 63.76<br />

(49.23) (49.15) (48.21) , (48.12) (46.2a (38.53)<br />

Sugarcane 1.40 1.58 1.58 1.55 1.99 2.46 2.78<br />

(4.7) (5.9) (5.6) I (8.0) (6.7) (6.8)<br />

Total 8.3 9.01 10.04 10.20 13.0 13.56 15.85<br />

Oilseeds (10.0) (9.6) (10.1) I (7.9) (11.0) (9.9)<br />

Horticulture 1.6 1.77 2.22 2.89 3.7 5.38<br />

(14.8) (11.3) .. (17.3) (18.4) (17.7) (22.7)<br />

-<br />

Note:<br />

i. Figures are the percentage <strong>of</strong> area under the crop (group) to total gross cropped area<br />

ii. Figures in Parenthesis are the Share <strong>of</strong> value <strong>of</strong> crops to total Value <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Output in India@ 1993-94 prices<br />

Source: India stat, National Account Statistics, Various issues, <strong>and</strong> Mythili G, 2006<br />

The pace <strong>of</strong> increase in the share <strong>of</strong> oil seeds <strong>and</strong> sugarcane in the GCA has been<br />

slow, whereas the proportion <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops in the GCA has been increasing<br />

rapidly. The area under oilseeds <strong>and</strong> sugarcane has increased from 8.3% <strong>and</strong> 1-40%<br />

respectively in triennium ending (TE) 1950-51 to 15.85 % <strong>and</strong> 2.78 % in TE 2005-06.<br />

Substantial growth in area under oilseeds was observed in the post 1980s as a result <strong>of</strong><br />

Technology Mission on Oilseeds (TMO). The share <strong>of</strong>fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetable sector in total<br />

area increased from 1.60 % in TE 1950-51 to 5.38% in TE 1999-00. There picture is<br />

different in regard to the extent <strong>of</strong> dominance <strong>of</strong> a few sectors in Indian agriculture when<br />

contribution <strong>of</strong> crops value in the agricultural output is considered. The contribution <strong>of</strong><br />

ffd grains declined drastically from 49% in TE 1950-51 to 38% in TE 2000-01,<br />

65


whereas, the contribution <strong>of</strong> fiuits <strong>and</strong> vegetables increased significantly fiuro 14.8 % to<br />

22.7 % during the same period. Higher output contribution <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops, despite<br />

less area coverage reflects the high potential <strong>of</strong> this sector for improving agricultural<br />

growth in India.<br />

3.2.2 Diversity <strong>and</strong> Spread in the Cropping Pattern<br />

The biological conditions <strong>of</strong> any region dictate, to a great extent, the initial pattern<br />

<strong>of</strong> crop mix. However, other economic, technological <strong>and</strong> marketing factors bring in the<br />

change in the pattern <strong>of</strong> diversification. VariOllS indices <strong>of</strong> diversification are computed<br />

for the past three decades <strong>and</strong> trends in different pattern <strong>of</strong> the same are presented.<br />

The extent <strong>of</strong> diversity is reflected in the number <strong>of</strong> crops produced in a state as<br />

well as by the aggregate level <strong>of</strong> spread in cropping pattern. The results show that most 0 f<br />

the states in the northern region have less diverse agriculture (table 3.2). These states<br />

produce mainly food grain crops. Southern region is the most diverse as most <strong>of</strong> the states<br />

produces large number <strong>of</strong> crops with Kamataka producing the highest number <strong>of</strong> crops.<br />

Due to different climatic conditions, many plantation crops are produced in this region<br />

which cannot be produced in other regions. Strikingly, the eastern region, which is<br />

characterised as having low level <strong>of</strong> irrigation <strong>and</strong> humid climate, is relatively more<br />

diverse in their cropping pattern <strong>and</strong> produces large number <strong>of</strong> foodgrain crops <strong>and</strong><br />

vegetable crops. In the western region, excepting Maharashtra, states are less diverse.<br />

Diversity in cropping pattern reflects only a partial picture <strong>of</strong> diversification. ]t is<br />

necessary to look at the distribution pattern in terms <strong>of</strong> spread <strong>and</strong> concentration <strong>of</strong><br />

cropping sector.<br />

66


Table 3.2: N urn b ero fC rops Produced by States in In dia<br />

St.te<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> <strong>Crops</strong><br />

Northern ROEion<br />

Jammu & Kashmir 13<br />

Puniab 14<br />

Harvana 15<br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> 16<br />

Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong> 19<br />

E.stern ROEion<br />

Bihar 20<br />

West Bengal 23<br />

Assam 24<br />

Orrisa 24<br />

Western Region<br />

Rajasthan 18<br />

Gujarat 19<br />

Madhya <strong>Pradesh</strong> 19<br />

Maharashtra 23<br />

Southern Region<br />

Kerala 18<br />

Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong><br />

2S<br />

Karnataka 27<br />

Tamil Nadu 24<br />

..<br />

Source: CMIE, <strong>and</strong> indIan Agncultural StatIstICS (Vanous Issues)<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> is also reflected in the spread <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern. Herfindahl Index<br />

is chosen as an index <strong>of</strong> spread or concentration in the cropping pattern. The range <strong>of</strong><br />

Herfmdahl index is from zero to one, where zero means full concentration i.e., entire area<br />

under one crop, <strong>and</strong> the value <strong>of</strong> Herfindahl index at one signifies full spread or that area<br />

is evenly distributed across crops. In terms <strong>of</strong>Herfmdahl index, states in the northern <strong>and</strong><br />

the eastern regions exhibit higher level <strong>of</strong> concentration (table 3.3). In the northern<br />

regions, only two crops i.e., rice <strong>and</strong> wheat dominate the cropping pattern, whereas in the<br />

eastern region, most <strong>of</strong> the cropped area is under rice. Both southern <strong>and</strong> western regions<br />

exhibit higher level <strong>of</strong> spread in cropping pattern with few exceptions. This is primarily<br />

because these regions have also allocated considerable area to pulses, oilseeds <strong>and</strong><br />

horticultural crops. No single crop dominates the cropping pattern in these regions. It is<br />

not strictly the case that the states with large number <strong>of</strong> crops also have higher index <strong>of</strong><br />

spread.<br />

67


Tabe I 33 . : T ren d· 1m S ~rea d or C oncentration ID Croppin2 Patt em by Indian States<br />

States I TE 1972 ~ TE 1982 TE 1992 TE 2002<br />

Nortbern Region<br />

Jammu & Kashmir 0.703 0.721 0.717 0.718<br />

Haryana 0.825 0.800 0.791 0.757<br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> Pradesb 0.711 0.664 0.646 0.645<br />

Punjab 0.749 0.660 0.634 0.612<br />

Uttar Pradesb 0.833 0.779 0.760 0.733<br />

Eastern Region<br />

Qrrisa 0.332 0.499 0.317 0.280<br />

Assam 0.425 0.489 0.458 0.460<br />

Bihar 0.517 0.468 0.450 0.427<br />

West Bengal 0.385 0.434 0.417 0.476<br />

Western R"1tion<br />

Madhya <strong>Pradesh</strong> 0.855 0.836 0.823 0.817<br />

Gujarat 0.834 0.863 0.875 0.863<br />

Maharashtra 0.795 0.797 0.819 0.838<br />

Rajasthan 0.796 0.805 0.816 0.786<br />

Soutbern R"1tion<br />

Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong> 0.801 0.802 0.798 0.838<br />

Karnataka 0.874 0.873 0.888 0.904<br />

Tamil Nadu 0.768 0.767 0.785 0.819<br />

Kerala 0.780 0.798 0.792 0.782<br />

Note:<br />

i. The levels <strong>of</strong> spread are measured by Herfindahllodex tbat range from 0-I, 0 being full concentration<br />

<strong>and</strong> 1 means spread in cropping pattern<br />

Source: CMIE, <strong>and</strong> lodian Agricultural Statistics (Various Issues)<br />

On the basis <strong>of</strong> the changing pattern <strong>of</strong> spread or concentration over a period <strong>of</strong><br />

time, three broad patterns can be noticed. The first pattern includes states that have shown<br />

almost no significant change in their index. Three states, Jammu <strong>and</strong> Kashmir, Kerala <strong>and</strong><br />

Rajasthan have been exhibiting stagnancy in their index <strong>of</strong> spread or concentration.<br />

Among these states, though Kerala experienced considerable change in the cropping<br />

pattern mix over the given time period, it did not resulted in changing the concentration<br />

index <strong>of</strong> the state. In the second pattern, states are moving towards higher level <strong>of</strong><br />

concentration in the cropping pattern. These include states from northern regions like<br />

Punjab, Haryana <strong>and</strong> Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong>. They increased considerable area under rice <strong>and</strong><br />

wheat crops after the introduction <strong>of</strong> Green Revolution. The trend <strong>of</strong> shift in the cropping<br />

pattern towards these specialized crops continued even during 1990s. The third category<br />

consists <strong>of</strong> the regions that are increasing their spread among the crops. Most <strong>of</strong> the<br />

68


southern states come under this category. This is specifically because these states are able<br />

to diversifY towards non-traditional crops including oilseeds <strong>and</strong> horticultural crops.<br />

3.2.3 L<strong>and</strong> Allocation in Favour <strong>of</strong> Higb Value <strong>Crops</strong><br />

L<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> non-food crops is used as a proxy to measure<br />

diversification. Greater the share <strong>of</strong> non-food crops in the gross cropped area, higher is<br />

the diversification. The temporal picture <strong>of</strong> change in absolute area under these crop<br />

groups shows an interesting picture. Haryana <strong>and</strong> Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong> (so-called specialized<br />

states in India), along with Rajasthan, Gujarat <strong>and</strong> Bihar, have increased the allocation <strong>of</strong><br />

area under both the crop groups i.e., rice/wheat <strong>and</strong> non-food crops (see table 3.4 <strong>and</strong><br />

appendix 3.2). They have replaced other inferior food crops like pulses in order to<br />

increase the overall allocation <strong>of</strong> non-food crops in their cropping pattern. In contrast<br />

Punjab increased the allocation <strong>of</strong> rice <strong>and</strong> wheat by reducing area under other high value<br />

non-food crops. West Bengal, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, Jammu <strong>and</strong> Kashmir, Assam<br />

<strong>and</strong> Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong> reduced the proportion <strong>of</strong> area under rice or wheat in order to<br />

increase area under non-food crops. Both the northern <strong>and</strong> the eastern regions could<br />

increase the share <strong>of</strong> non-food crops only marginally. It is mostly the southern <strong>and</strong><br />

western regions that increased the share <strong>of</strong> non-food crops in the GCA to a great extent.<br />

We also measured the growth rate <strong>of</strong> area under these crops in order to find the relative<br />

role <strong>of</strong> growth in area under crops <strong>and</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> area under cultivation in changing<br />

relative weights <strong>of</strong> crops (appendix 3.3. 3.4 <strong>and</strong> 35). More interestingly, four states<br />

(Kerala, Assam, Tamil Nadu <strong>and</strong> J&K) experienced negative growth in the area under<br />

non-food crops during 1990s but, the relative share <strong>of</strong> these crops increased in the gross<br />

cropped area. In addition, two states (UP <strong>and</strong> Maharashtra) experienced lower rate <strong>of</strong><br />

growth in area under non-food crops during 1990s as compared to 1980s but the relative<br />

weight <strong>of</strong> non-food crops in the gross cropped area increased during 1990s.<br />

69


T a bl e 34' , , Sh a r eo iN 00-F 00 de rops 'G ID ross C ropped Area io India<br />

Regions TE 1972 TE 1982 I TE 1992 I TE2002<br />

Northern Rtl!ion<br />

-Harvana 13.35 15.90 24.34<br />

24.27<br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> 4.53 4.11 4.09<br />

5.&4<br />

Punjab 19.88 15.24 12.84<br />

10.49<br />

Jammu <strong>and</strong> Kashmir 5.28 7.22 7.80<br />

7.90<br />

Utlar <strong>Pradesh</strong> 13.26 13.66 15.07<br />

15.65<br />

Eastern Ret!ion<br />

Assam 2\.94 24.94 24.19<br />

24.65<br />

Bihar 9.02 9.54 10.51<br />

9.95<br />

Orrisa 10.66 17.27 10.45<br />

9.59<br />

West Ben2a1 12.81 17.32 19.03<br />

22.18<br />

Western Ret!ion<br />

Gujara( 48.25 49.43 53.62<br />

59.19<br />

Madhya <strong>Pradesh</strong> 18.13 13.92 15.71<br />

14.35<br />

Maharashtra 25.25 27.05 26.64<br />

28.83<br />

Rajasthan 12.81 15.86 25.62<br />

22.36<br />

Southern Region<br />

Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong> 27.43 32.01 43.87<br />

42.81<br />

Kamataka 32.75 31.24 33.10<br />

3\.66<br />

Kerala 66.10 69.06 79.90<br />

87.34<br />

Tamil Nadu 3\.81 33.04 42.36<br />

42.59<br />

Note.<br />

i. Non-food crops include crops other than all cereals <strong>and</strong> pulses<br />

Source: CMIE, <strong>and</strong> ' lndian Agricultural Statistics (Various Issues)<br />

3.3 Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Income-Risk Pattern<br />

3.3.1. Trend in Income <strong>and</strong> Risk in Agriculture<br />

The gross value <strong>of</strong> output per hectare <strong>of</strong> the selected thirty crops is used as a proxy<br />

to income from agriculture, <strong>and</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation in the gross value <strong>of</strong> output as a proxy<br />

for risk. Since, the initial differences in the gross value <strong>of</strong> output across states is expected<br />

to differ according to the initial conditions <strong>and</strong> other bio-physical factors, for the purpose<br />

<strong>of</strong> comparison, we have used the changing relative ranks <strong>of</strong> the states by their gross value<br />

<strong>of</strong> output per hectare over the last three decades (the levels <strong>of</strong> gross value <strong>of</strong> output are<br />

given in appendix 3.6). The regions exhibiting higher extent <strong>of</strong> concentration (Punjab <strong>and</strong><br />

Haryana) indeed have improved their relative ranking. More importantly, another highly<br />

specialized state i.e. Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong> retained the first position throughout the decades<br />

(table 3.5). The eastem <strong>and</strong> the southern regions, like Orrisa, Bihar, Kerala <strong>and</strong> Tamil<br />

Nadu have shown decline their ranking. The latter two states have substituted huge<br />

70


amount <strong>of</strong> area from food crops to non-food crops. This shows that merely increasing the<br />

share <strong>of</strong> area under non-food crops is not sufficient to increase income <strong>and</strong> that there are<br />

other important factors involved. Among the western region, Gujarat <strong>and</strong> MP have<br />

slipped in their ranking while both Maharashtra <strong>and</strong> Rajasthan could improve their<br />

ranking.<br />

T abe I 35 . : Ra n ki ~o fS tates A ccor d' 102 to Gross Value <strong>of</strong>Ou put per ba @ 1993-94 prices<br />

Siaies Rank in TE Rank in TE RankinTE Rankin TE<br />

1972 1982 1992 2002<br />

Northern Region<br />

Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong> I 1 1 1<br />

Haryana 13 13 12 \I<br />

Punjab 11 5 3 4<br />

Himacbal <strong>Pradesh</strong> 17 17 17 17<br />

Jammu & Kashmir 16 16 16 16<br />

Eastern Region<br />

Bihar 7 \0 11 12<br />

Orrisa 14 14 14 IS<br />

Assam 15 15 15 14<br />

West Bengal 8 9 7 6<br />

Western Region<br />

Gujarat 5 4 \0 10<br />

Madhya <strong>Pradesh</strong> 3 6 5 8<br />

Maharashtra 9 3 4 3<br />

Rajasthan 12 11 9 9<br />

Southern R


including Jammu <strong>and</strong> Kashmir, Kerala <strong>and</strong> <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> are the oncs with lesser<br />

variability in output. It is important to note that the highest growth in the gross value <strong>of</strong><br />

output during 1980s was accompanied by higher variability <strong>of</strong> the same. How different<br />

pattern <strong>of</strong> diversification resulted in different income <strong>and</strong> risk scenario is the subject <strong>of</strong><br />

investigation in the next section.<br />

Table 3.6: Coefficient <strong>of</strong> Variation in Gross Value <strong>of</strong> Output (jiJ 1993-94 pric es<br />

States I 1970. 1980. I 19900 ABDecades<br />

Northern Rq;on<br />

Puniab 16.63 14.40 7.18 31.10<br />

Harvana 19.34 17.31 7.81 34.25<br />

Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong> 10.05 9.05 7.05 26.24<br />

Jammu & Kashmir 10.39 9.26 8.00 15.04<br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> 7.76 13.14 8.08 1750<br />

Eastern R ... ion<br />

Bihar 9.37 14.04 12.04 18.99<br />

Assam 6.38 6.46 6.36 20.64<br />

Orrisa 13.45 16.73 15.66 21.10<br />

West Ben2a1 8.93 19.86 11.20 32.79<br />

Western Rq;on<br />

Madhva <strong>Pradesh</strong> 15.89 10.78 16.68 26.32<br />

Maharashtra 22.83 14.20 13.40 29.19<br />

Guiarat 24.76 30.62 24.97 31.79<br />

Raiasthan 17.43 19.63 16.35 34.67<br />

Southern ROI!ion<br />

Tamil Nadu 10.92 16.03 10.57 26.91<br />

Kerala 5.15 7.64 8.10 14.63<br />

Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong> 12.94 14.85 10.98 28.26<br />

Kamataka 10.19 11.01 13.90 29.84<br />

India 8.62 10.87 7.69 25.78<br />

Source: Central Stallsbcal OrganIzatIon (Vanous Issues)<br />

3.3.2. Link <strong>of</strong> Pattern <strong>of</strong> Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> with Income <strong>and</strong><br />

Risk<br />

The pattern <strong>of</strong> diversification influences income <strong>and</strong> risk, but the impact <strong>of</strong> the<br />

same may differ according to the components <strong>of</strong> diversification. It is important to note<br />

states differ in terms <strong>of</strong> their magnitude <strong>of</strong> shift in their concentration index or changing<br />

share <strong>of</strong> area under non·food crops. Therefore, their link with income <strong>and</strong> risk needs<br />

\<br />

further exploration.<br />

72


We have grouped the states on the basis <strong>of</strong> their pattern <strong>of</strong> diversification. When<br />

diversification pertain to _spread in the cropping pattern, we have three broad groups;<br />

states- increasing spread, increasing concentration <strong>and</strong> showing no significant change in<br />

either spread or concentration in their cropping pattern (appendix 3.7). When<br />

diversification is measured as l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> non-food crops, we again have<br />

three broad groups; states- increasing share <strong>of</strong> non-food crops, declining share <strong>of</strong> food<br />

crops <strong>and</strong> showing no significant change in share <strong>of</strong> food crops in their GCA (appendix<br />

3.8).<br />

The pattern <strong>of</strong> the rate <strong>of</strong> growth in income <strong>and</strong> its variability illustrates that the<br />

group <strong>of</strong> states, which did not change significantly the index <strong>of</strong> concentration, performed<br />

better during 1970s <strong>and</strong> 1980s, but experienced negative growth in their income during<br />

the 1990s (table 3.7). More importantly, they also faced highest variability in their returns<br />

through all the decades. The states, which increased their concentration on few crops<br />

during the decade <strong>of</strong> 1980s experienced high growth in income. Most <strong>of</strong> these states<br />

followed the Green Revolution <strong>and</strong> thereby experienced high growth in productivity <strong>of</strong><br />

crops. Interestingly, these states experienced decline in their growth <strong>of</strong> income during<br />

1990s, indicating the declining impact <strong>of</strong> Green Revolution. Increase in the spread <strong>of</strong><br />

cropping pattern was not much beneficial until 1990s. However, it is found that these<br />

groups <strong>of</strong> states achieved relatively higher growth in income during 1990s. Increase in<br />

spread <strong>of</strong> crops was mainly due to increasing share <strong>of</strong> non-food crops in the GCA. More<br />

interestingly, increasing spread was linked with low variability in return during all the<br />

three decades. This means that risk arising due to market <strong>and</strong> weather conditions could be<br />

neutralised by increasing diversity in the cropping pattern.<br />

73


Table 3.7: Growth <strong>and</strong> Variability <strong>of</strong> Income According to Spread <strong>and</strong><br />

Concentration<br />

-<br />

0 fC roppmg P attern<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> Group <strong>of</strong> States Group <strong>of</strong> States showing Group <strong>of</strong> States<br />

showing no change increase in Coucentration showing increase in<br />

in Concentration <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern spread <strong>of</strong> cropping<br />

Index<br />

pattern<br />

CGR in GrOll Value <strong>of</strong> Output per ha at 1993-94 prices<br />

1970. 3.03 1.36 1.24<br />

1980. 2.77 3.59 1.80<br />

1990. -0.17 1.47 2.53<br />

VariabiliQ in Income (Coefficient <strong>of</strong> Variation (CV)<strong>of</strong> Gross Value <strong>of</strong> Output at 1993-94 prices)<br />

1970. 11.31 8.63 10.30<br />

1980. 13.54 13.94 12.37<br />

1990. 11.39 8.92 7.35<br />

..<br />

Source: CMIE, <strong>and</strong> Indian Agncultural Stallstlcs (Vanous Issues)<br />

The results <strong>of</strong> interplay between changing share <strong>of</strong> non-food crops income <strong>and</strong> risk<br />

are presented in table 3.8. The results indicate that greater thrust towards non-food grains<br />

is beneficial for the agricultural economy <strong>of</strong> the regions in India. The regions which<br />

shifted their cropping pattern towards non-food crops have been consistently performing<br />

well through all the decades. They gained in terms <strong>of</strong> achieving higher growth in their<br />

income. But, this gain becomes more perceptible only in the post liberalization era in<br />

India as the growth achieved was highest among all groups during this period. It was in<br />

the 1980s that states which increased allocation <strong>of</strong> food crops in their cropping pattern<br />

could achieve higher growth. But, that process did not continue to benefit these groups <strong>of</strong><br />

states as they experienced poor growth in income during 1990s. The regions that have not<br />

experienced any significant change in area under non-food crops registered poor growth<br />

in output <strong>and</strong> hence lagged behind in the process <strong>of</strong> agricultural development. But, in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> the variability <strong>of</strong> returns, it is important to note that regions shifted their<br />

cropping pattern towards non-food crops experienced highest variability <strong>of</strong> returns,<br />

especially during 1980s <strong>and</strong> 1990s. The variability <strong>of</strong>returns declined in all the states<br />

during 19908; however, those states, which reduced the share <strong>of</strong> area under non-food<br />

crops experienced low variability <strong>of</strong> returns as compared to other states, during the<br />

period.<br />

74


Table 3.8: Growth <strong>and</strong> Variability <strong>of</strong> Income According to <strong>Diversification</strong> towards<br />

N 00-F 00 -de<br />

rops<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> Group <strong>of</strong> State. Group <strong>of</strong> States showing no Group <strong>of</strong> States<br />

reducing<br />

Share <strong>of</strong> change in Share <strong>of</strong> area increasing Share <strong>of</strong> area<br />

area under non-food under non-food crops under non-food crops<br />

crops<br />

CGR in Gross Value <strong>of</strong> Output per ba at 1993-94 prices<br />

1970. 2.03 2.08 1.34<br />

1980s 3.11 1.37 2.05<br />

1990s 1.35 1.71 2.44<br />

Variability in Income (Coefficient <strong>of</strong> Variation (CYl<strong>of</strong> Gross Value <strong>of</strong> Output at 1993-94 prices)<br />

1970. 10.03 10.23 7.87<br />

1980s 11.33 10.70 13.63<br />

1990s 6.34 6.73 11.21<br />

..<br />

Source: CMIE, <strong>and</strong> IndIan Agncultural StatistIcs (Vanous Issues)<br />

3.4. Relationship between Changing Cropping Pattern Mix <strong>and</strong><br />

Growth <strong>of</strong> Crop Output<br />

Growth in aggregate output <strong>of</strong> the agricultural sector is influenced by the level <strong>of</strong><br />

technology, infrastructure, government policies <strong>and</strong> crop pattern, among others. Changes in<br />

cropping pattern help to accommodate risks originating from various factors as well as to<br />

optimize income either by reducing cost or increasing efficiency. In an aggregate picture,<br />

any change in cropping pattern also causes a shift in the aggregate production function <strong>of</strong><br />

the sector <strong>and</strong> the process <strong>of</strong> diversification is responsible for this. We initially examined<br />

the trends in the growth <strong>of</strong> output across states in India, followed by an investigation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

relative significance <strong>of</strong> various components <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> output, including diversification<br />

from low value crops to high value crops. The decomposition model is used to examine the<br />

contribution <strong>of</strong> each component relative to each other. Finally, factors that influenced the<br />

nature <strong>and</strong> direction <strong>of</strong> diversification in India are examined.<br />

3.4.1. Trends in Growth <strong>of</strong> Crop Output in States <strong>of</strong> India<br />

The trends in growth <strong>of</strong> output across states in the past two decades reveal that few<br />

states have been able to experience higher output growth during the 1980s <strong>and</strong> 1990s<br />

~able<br />

3.9). West Bengal, <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> <strong>and</strong> Maharashtra were able to achieve<br />

75


growth rate above the India's average growth <strong>of</strong> output during both the decades. It is<br />

important to note that considerable area in these states is under high value horticultural<br />

crops. These states also experienced high growth in area under these crops during both<br />

the decades l4 • Some states i.e., Bihar, Jammu & Kashmir <strong>and</strong> Karnataka were able to<br />

improve their growth during 1990s over that <strong>of</strong> the 1980s. These states however did not<br />

benefit from the technological initiatives taken by the government as part <strong>of</strong> Green<br />

Revolution <strong>and</strong> TMO but have shown signs <strong>of</strong> development after the liberalization <strong>of</strong> the<br />

economy. Strangely, the major agricultural states, Punjab, Haryana <strong>and</strong> Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong>,<br />

which gained enormously from Green Revolution experienced decline in growth rates<br />

during 1990s. These regions had shifted significant amount <strong>of</strong> area towards few selected<br />

crops like rice <strong>and</strong> wheat after the introduction <strong>of</strong> High Yielding Varieties. Consequently,<br />

they showed significant improvement in the growth <strong>of</strong> output. But, there were signs <strong>of</strong><br />

fatigue in the technological development <strong>of</strong> these crops that resulted in dampened growth<br />

during 199Os. Some states continued to exhibit poor growth during both the decades <strong>and</strong><br />

have not been able to benefit either from either Green Revolution or liberalization regime<br />

such as Assam, Kerala <strong>and</strong> Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong>. At the same time, there are a few regions<br />

which did not gain from Green Revolution, but have picked up growth in the recent past.<br />

Such a distinct pattern <strong>of</strong> growth across region <strong>and</strong> time makes it imperative to quantify<br />

the major components <strong>of</strong> growth in the regions across time.<br />

14 This is evident from the growth rate in area under horticultural crops <strong>and</strong> their proportion in the area<br />

under cultivation Ihe details <strong>of</strong> which are presented in the next chapter <strong>of</strong> the thesis<br />

76


Tb39T a Ie . : ren d' ID t h e Growth Rates <strong>of</strong>CropOutputin States *<br />

High Agriculture growth States (in %)<br />

StatesIY ear 1980s StatesIYear 19905<br />

West Bengal 5.76 Bihar 4.27<br />

Punjab 5.16 West Bengal 3.85<br />

Haryana 4.44 <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> 3.69<br />

Rajasthan 4.31 Maharashtra 3.65<br />

Maharashtra 3.85 Jammu & Kashmir 3.45<br />

Madhya <strong>Pradesh</strong> 3.65 Kamataka 3.26<br />

Tamil Nadu 3.49<br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> 3.46<br />

Low Agriculture growth States (in %)<br />

StatesIY ear 1980s StatesIY ear 1990s<br />

Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong> 2.93 Assam 2.75<br />

Kerala 2.05 Rajasthan 2.7<br />

Bihar 2.60 Haryana 2.67<br />

Karnataka 2.5 Kerala 2.62<br />

Assam 2.39 Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong> 2.34<br />

Andhra<strong>Pradesh</strong> 2.3 Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong> 2.21<br />

Orrisa 1.46 Tamil Nadu 2.11<br />

Jammu & Kashmir 1.2 Guiarat 1.81<br />

Gujarat -0.81 Punjab 1.27<br />

Orrisa 0.46<br />

Madhya <strong>Pradesh</strong> -0.03<br />

• Compound growth rate<br />

Source: Central Statistical Organization (Various Issues)<br />

3.4.2. Model for Identification <strong>of</strong> Role <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> in<br />

Growth <strong>of</strong> Crop Output<br />

In order to underst<strong>and</strong> the full impact <strong>of</strong> diversification, it is necessary to approach<br />

through decomposition <strong>of</strong> the rates <strong>of</strong> growth that not only provides the contributions <strong>of</strong><br />

the components <strong>of</strong> growth but also helps to indicate their relative positions.<br />

Decomposition model helps in identifying the factors responsible for the observed growth<br />

<strong>of</strong> output in different regions. Such analyses <strong>of</strong> past experience <strong>and</strong> comparative studies<br />

<strong>of</strong> regions with different rates <strong>of</strong> growth, in particular, could provide valuable insights<br />

into factors, other than purely technological growth, which help or impede exploitation <strong>of</strong><br />

known possibilities. This insight, in turn, might indicate changes in programmes <strong>and</strong><br />

77


policies which could make agricultural planning more effective (Minhas <strong>and</strong><br />

Vaidyanathan, 1965).<br />

The decomposition model introduced by Minhas <strong>and</strong> Vaidyanathan (1965) was<br />

used to explain the components <strong>of</strong> output growth across regions in India. The observed<br />

change in aggregate output was decomposed into four component elements- i.e.,<br />

contribution <strong>of</strong> (i) changes in area (ii) changes in per acre yields (iii) changes in cropping<br />

pattern <strong>and</strong> (iv) the interaction <strong>of</strong> the latter two elements. The scheme <strong>of</strong> decomposition<br />

initially looked at the absolute changes in the value <strong>of</strong> gross agricultural output,<br />

QrQo~ At~lIctY ctPe - A;i:.1Ico Y coPe ----------------------------------------------------1<br />

which can be further extended as<br />

Where<br />

-------------------------------------------------------------2<br />

Qt <strong>and</strong> Q. ~ Value <strong>of</strong> gross agricultural output at constant prices (P) during period-t <strong>and</strong><br />

during base period-O respectively<br />

At <strong>and</strong> Ao = Gross cropped area during period-t <strong>and</strong> during base period-O respectively<br />

IIct <strong>and</strong> 8co= (Acl At) = proportion <strong>of</strong> area under crop-c (Act) to the gross cropped area (At)<br />

during period-t <strong>and</strong> during base period-O respectively<br />

Y ct <strong>and</strong> Y e.~ physical output per acre <strong>of</strong> crop-c during period-t <strong>and</strong> during base period-O<br />

respectively<br />

P, = price <strong>of</strong> the crop--c.<br />

The first three components <strong>of</strong> the model represent the cOlitribution <strong>of</strong> change in<br />

area, yield <strong>and</strong> cropping pattern or diversification in absolute change in the value <strong>of</strong> gross<br />

akcultural output. The first element on the right side <strong>of</strong> the equation is the area effect.<br />

78


That is, an increase in output <strong>of</strong> this magnitude could have taken place in the absence <strong>of</strong><br />

any changes in per acre crop yields <strong>and</strong> the crop pattern. The second elernent in the<br />

equation is the effect <strong>of</strong> yield changes for a constant crop pattern. The third element<br />

portrays the effects <strong>of</strong> change in crop pattern in the absence <strong>of</strong> any change in per acre<br />

crop yields. The fourth or last element shows interaction effect <strong>of</strong> changes in yield <strong>and</strong><br />

cropping pattern in the growth <strong>of</strong> output. It reflects whether or not the crops, whose<br />

relative weight in the cropping pattern is increasing has also been experiencing positive<br />

growth in productivity or yield. ]t is important to note that the components (area, yield,<br />

cropping pattern & interactions) do not convey a misleading impression <strong>of</strong> causation in<br />

any way but explains only a particular form in which the growth <strong>of</strong> output has taken place<br />

in the past. The interaction terms are obtained because <strong>of</strong> the multiplicative nature <strong>of</strong> the<br />

identity.<br />

There are two components related to diversification or shift in cropping pattern. The<br />

first term (third element) is called "static" diversification effect <strong>and</strong> second term (fourth<br />

element) is called "dynamic" diversification effect. The frrst term shows static effects lS<br />

since it becomes more positive when the area under crops whose yields were initially<br />

(during the base period) high, increases relatively as compared to other crops. In contrast,<br />

the second term shows dynamic effects 16 because it turns out to be more positive when<br />

the area under the crops whose yields are improving, increases relative to the area under<br />

other crops, whose yields are decreasing or stagnant. The maximum potential for the<br />

static diversification effects depends on the initial level <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern <strong>and</strong> the range<br />

<strong>of</strong> feasible crop shares that can be grown under agronomic constraints. The maximum<br />

potential for the dynamic shift-effects depends on the same factors as for the static<br />

effects, <strong>and</strong> the response <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern to changes in productivity <strong>of</strong> the crop<br />

(Kurosaki, 2(03).<br />

Most <strong>of</strong> the studies that employed decomposition models for explaining the<br />

components <strong>of</strong> growth did concentrate mainly on the static effects <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>and</strong><br />

" Nole that in


productivity growth (Joshi, 2005, Bhatia <strong>and</strong> Sinha, 1975, Kalamkar, 2005). The dynamic<br />

effect, which is captured through the interaction effect, is ignored. It denote the<br />

concomitant changes in the components <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> output, i.e., change in cropping<br />

pattern <strong>and</strong> productivity <strong>of</strong> the crops. As noted, diversification may affect the growth<br />

through static <strong>and</strong> dynamic effects. A positive static effect <strong>of</strong> diversification would show<br />

a shift <strong>of</strong> crop structure in favour <strong>of</strong> high initial productivity crops. This does not capture<br />

development in technology <strong>of</strong> crops which may change over time <strong>and</strong> may alter relative<br />

values <strong>of</strong> crops. In other words, over-time, the pr<strong>of</strong>itability or relative values <strong>of</strong> crops<br />

does not remain constant. Also change in the productivity <strong>of</strong> crops may change the<br />

comparative advantage <strong>of</strong> crops. Hence, it is important to consider the dynamic effects <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification i.e., the concomitant movements <strong>of</strong> yield <strong>and</strong> cropping pattern change.<br />

The dynamic aspect <strong>of</strong> diversification indicates the impact <strong>of</strong> the joint movements in the<br />

diversification <strong>of</strong> crop pattern <strong>and</strong> technological change on overall output change. A<br />

positive dynamic effect <strong>of</strong> diversification would imply that the crop structure has shifted<br />

in favour <strong>of</strong> those crops which show relatively higher growth in yield. In a similar way,<br />

negative dynamic effect implies over-time, cropping pattern shifts in favour <strong>of</strong> those<br />

crops which could not experience higher growth in productivity. This is the growthdepressive<br />

impact <strong>of</strong> diversification on output in the agricultural sector.<br />

3.4.3. Components <strong>of</strong> Growth <strong>of</strong> Crop Output in India<br />

Respective contribution <strong>of</strong> area, yield <strong>and</strong> changes in cropping pattern to the gross<br />

crop output across regions are computed for four broad regions. The relative significance<br />

<strong>of</strong> each component in the growth <strong>of</strong> output has implications for future agricultural<br />

policies. If the growth stems from technological change (yield improvements),<br />

investments in research <strong>and</strong> extension need to be accorded priority. The area-driven<br />

growth implies need for greater extension efforts to make agriculture broad based. If the<br />

growth occurs due to crop diversification. there is a need for increasing investments in<br />

development <strong>of</strong> market <strong>and</strong> infrastructure (Joshi, 2005).<br />

80


Table 3.10: Contribution <strong>of</strong> Different Components in Growth <strong>of</strong> Gross Value <strong>of</strong> OUtpllt<br />

by Rfltions in India<br />

Region Period Area <strong>Diversification</strong> Aggregate <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

Effect effect (Static) Yield effect effect (Dynamic)<br />

North 1970s 28.45 08.65 54.34 08.56<br />

I 980s 10.35 11.54 72.54 05.57<br />

1990s 22.54 18.54 53.25 05.67<br />

East<br />

All decades 23.45 12.65 60.12 03.78<br />

1970s 43.65 30.15 30.78 -04.58<br />

1980s 24.56 08.36 73.80 -06.72<br />

1990s 45.25 07.10 45.35 02.30<br />

West<br />

All decades 23.15 10.05 64.00 02.80<br />

I 970s 18.33 23.85 58.64 -00.82<br />

1980s 15.48 31.07 51.54 01.91<br />

1990s -15.85 77.65 38.45 -00.25<br />

South<br />

All decades 19.95 48.25 30.54 01.26<br />

1970s -20.85 30.04 87.05 03.76<br />

1980s 04.34 38.65 52.15 04.86<br />

1990s -11.00 76.54 35.26 -00.80<br />

India<br />

All decades -04.15 48.56 58.45 -02.86<br />

1970s 19.78 14.66 62.12 03.44<br />

1980s 14.33 19.39 69.17 -02.89<br />

1990s 11.29 48.65 37.66 02.40<br />

Note.<br />

All decades 17.33 24.66 61.52 -03.51<br />

i. Figures arc in percentage<br />

Source: Computations based on the data obtained from Central Statistical Organization (Various Issues),<br />

CMIE. <strong>and</strong> Indian Agricultural Statistics (Various Issues)<br />

The results <strong>of</strong> the sources <strong>of</strong> growth suggests that, at the economy level, the<br />

significance <strong>of</strong> diversification or crop-pattern mix in the growth <strong>of</strong> output has been<br />

increasing over a period <strong>of</strong> time. The effect <strong>of</strong> diversification was low during the decades<br />

<strong>of</strong> I 970s <strong>and</strong> 1980s but increased significantly during the post-liberalization period (table<br />

3.\0). When the economy was closed, it was technological development that made the<br />

largest contribution to the output growth. The area <strong>and</strong> technology effect has slowed<br />

down; the contribution <strong>of</strong> technology effect to output growth declined dramatically from<br />

69 to 37 percent from 1980s to I 990s. The declining contribution <strong>of</strong> technology to output<br />

growth was compensated by improvements in the diversification effect in the Indian<br />

agricultural sector which increased from around 20 % during I 980s to 48% during 1990s.<br />

The region-wise picture exhibits a distinct assortment <strong>of</strong> components <strong>of</strong> growth<br />

acrors them. For the eastern region, the contribution <strong>of</strong> area stood at around 45 % to the<br />

81


change m growth <strong>of</strong> output during 1990s. It indicates that area expansion through<br />

extensification or intensification is still the major contribu~ing factor to output growth.<br />

This is a cause <strong>of</strong> concern as area expansion is the major source <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> output; this<br />

process is less viable <strong>and</strong> unsustainable in the long run. The trend in the other<br />

components <strong>of</strong> growth reflects the role <strong>of</strong> technology, which accounted for more than 70<br />

% change in the output growth during 1980s. It came down drastically during 1990s <strong>and</strong><br />

accounted for only 45% <strong>of</strong> variation in growth. Crop pattern shifts continue to play a<br />

minimal role in the growth <strong>of</strong> output, as this region continues to diversify towards highly<br />

specialized crop like rice. The agricultural sector <strong>of</strong> this region is dominated by rice with<br />

less diversification towards other high value non-food crops.<br />

In the northern zone, which benefited enormously from Green revolution <strong>and</strong><br />

devoted high amount <strong>of</strong> area towards high value food crops, technology contributed to<br />

major change in the growth <strong>of</strong> output. Although, crop pattern shift has been increasing<br />

over time, the contribution <strong>of</strong> the same is still low at around 18 %. Low diversification<br />

effect is attributed to the fact that the change in cropping pattern has resulted in increased<br />

specialisation towards crops like rice <strong>and</strong> wheat. At the same time, the yield <strong>of</strong> these<br />

crops in this region increased many-fold, which resulted in increased role <strong>of</strong>yield17. The<br />

area effect contributed around 22 % towards change in the output growth during 1990s.<br />

The percentage contribution was 10 % in the previous decade. Major concern is that like<br />

eastern region, the significance <strong>of</strong> area effect increased during the 1990s, while that <strong>of</strong><br />

technology declined drastically. This is also probably due to decline or stagnation in the<br />

yields <strong>of</strong> majority <strong>of</strong> the crops during 1990s as compared to 1980s.<br />

There is a huge contrast in terms <strong>of</strong> the relative role <strong>of</strong> components in southern <strong>and</strong><br />

western regions in comparison other regions. The contribution <strong>of</strong> crop diversification in<br />

the growth <strong>of</strong> output has been quite high <strong>and</strong> over time <strong>and</strong> the same is increasing at a<br />

fast pace. The share <strong>of</strong> diversification in the growth <strong>of</strong> output jumped from 31 % <strong>and</strong> 38<br />

" Yield effect is given by do'y, which signifies that yield effect increases as the yield <strong>of</strong> the specialized<br />

crop~ increases faster. This is because the change in per unit yield <strong>of</strong> crop is weighted by the relative<br />

weight <strong>of</strong> that crop in the total cropping pattern. Accordingly, diversification effect which is given by 'dyo<br />

Will bF higher if cropping pattern shifts more towards the crops which comm<strong>and</strong>s relatively high per unit<br />

Yldd luring the base period.<br />

82


% respectively in western <strong>and</strong> southern region during 1980s to more than 70010 during<br />

1990s. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the share <strong>of</strong> technology in growth declined from around 50%<br />

to nearly 35% in both the regions during the same period. Interestingly, both these<br />

regions are experiencing declining contribution <strong>of</strong> area in their output growth <strong>and</strong> its<br />

contribution became negative during 199Os. Decline in the area under cultivation was<br />

compensated by the increased shift in cropping pattern towards high value crops rather<br />

than by productivity growth, which added to the high effect <strong>of</strong> diversification.<br />

In a nutshell, technological development continues to be the major component <strong>of</strong><br />

growth in the northern region, though its effect is declining. This is primarily due to<br />

decline in the yield <strong>of</strong> a few specialized crops. Hence, other components <strong>of</strong> growth<br />

including diversification need attention. In the eastern region, area expansion is the major<br />

source <strong>of</strong> growth in the absence <strong>of</strong> any significant technological development <strong>and</strong> crop<br />

shifts. As avenues to increase area under cultivation are rather bleak, crop substitution<br />

towards high value crops <strong>and</strong> development in technology will have to be the potential<br />

source <strong>of</strong> growth in future in this region. In both the southern <strong>and</strong> western regions,<br />

diversification has become an important component for growth primarily due to the<br />

decline in area under cultivation <strong>and</strong> poor technological development.<br />

Despite variations in the relative contributions <strong>of</strong> components, the common feature<br />

that emerges from the decomposition analysis is that with notable exceptions, a<br />

significant portion <strong>of</strong> output growth in these regions is explained by change in crop<br />

pattern in tenos <strong>of</strong> relative weight <strong>of</strong> crops. And, its significance has been increasing over<br />

time. It is vital to note that change in the relative weights <strong>of</strong> crop is a function <strong>of</strong> the<br />

growth rate <strong>of</strong> area under the crop vis a vis growth in the cropped area. As noted, the<br />

pattern <strong>of</strong> changing relative weight <strong>and</strong> growth rate <strong>of</strong> area under crops indicates that four<br />

states (Kerala, Assam, Tamil Nadu <strong>and</strong> J&K) experienced negative growth <strong>of</strong> area under<br />

non-food crops during 19905, but the relative weight <strong>of</strong> non-food crops increased in the<br />

1990s. This raises the need to examine the trend in the growth <strong>of</strong> area under cultivation.<br />

The aggregate change in the cultivated area <strong>of</strong> a region can be segregated on the<br />

basis10f 'substitution' <strong>and</strong> 'expansion' effects by comparing the area growth rates <strong>of</strong><br />

83


individual crops with the corresponding growth rate in gross cropped area. In other<br />

words, the aggregate change in the cropping pattern in each region can be due to either<br />

substitution <strong>of</strong> area among crops or by expansion <strong>of</strong> area under cultivation. For<br />

measuring the trend in area expansion <strong>and</strong> substitution, we used the method by<br />

Venkataramanan <strong>and</strong> Prahladachar (1980). According to this method, an unchanged<br />

cropping pattern (no change in crop mix) can be a situation where the respective areas<br />

under aU crops bear the same proportion to the gross cropped area (GCA) over the years.<br />

It implies that the rate <strong>of</strong> growth in area under individual crops must equal the rate <strong>of</strong><br />

growth in the gross cropped area over the same time period. Such a change can be<br />

expressed in the form <strong>of</strong> a linear homogenous gross cropped area function, where given<br />

proportionate changes in area under individual crops are related to equal proportionate<br />

change in gross cropped area. The differences in the rates <strong>of</strong> growth in the area <strong>of</strong><br />

individual crops from the rate <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> GCA, therefore provide evidence <strong>of</strong> change in<br />

the cropping pattern. The total change in the cropping pattern over time is the sum total<br />

<strong>of</strong> the substitution effect (the relative decline in area under some crops <strong>and</strong> corresponding<br />

equivalent increase in area under other substitutable crops for a given gross cropped area)<br />

<strong>and</strong> the expansion effect (effect <strong>of</strong> increase in the gross cropped area).<br />

An analysis <strong>of</strong> the relative role <strong>of</strong> area expansion <strong>and</strong> area substitution in change in<br />

cropping pattern across four broad regions in India provides interesting insights (table<br />

3.11). The net change in area was negative during 1990s signifying that either there was<br />

decline in the area available for cultivation or that the level <strong>of</strong> cropping intensity<br />

decreased during this period. The decade <strong>of</strong> the 1980s saw increase in area expansion<br />

effect which declined during the 19905. The expansion <strong>of</strong> area faced decline during this<br />

period together with increased substitution <strong>of</strong> crops in the cropping pattern. It is<br />

important to note that the role <strong>of</strong> substitution effect in change in cropping pattern has<br />

been continuously increasing over a period <strong>of</strong> time. This indicates that the avenues for<br />

increasing growth through area expansion are rather dim <strong>and</strong> there is a need to look for<br />

other factors for stepping up growth. The region wise picture indicates that it is the<br />

northern region which has demonstrated strong area expansion, whereas the eastern<br />

regi,?n has shown poor performance in terms <strong>of</strong> area expansion as well as crop<br />

84


substitution. Interestingly, crop substitution is becoming more important in the western<br />

<strong>and</strong> s;outhem states. These states experienced negative net area change during the 199Os.<br />

The increased role <strong>of</strong> crop substitution along with decline in area for cultivation actually<br />

resulted in magnifying role <strong>of</strong> crop diversification in the growth <strong>of</strong> output in these<br />

regions.<br />

Tbl311A<br />

a e . : rea E xpanslOn an d S u b stitution . Efli eel ' ID I n d' la<br />

India Northern Eastern Western Southern<br />

Region Region Region Region<br />

Area E~.D5ion<br />

1970. 11683 5152 1957 3653 921<br />

1980. 13741 3528 2087 4850 3276<br />

1990s 12957 4028 1566 4506 2857<br />

Area Subslitulion<br />

1970. 10041 2595 1045 3487 2914<br />

1980. 11366 2483 886 4071 3926<br />

1990s 11632 1767 1234 46\0 4021<br />

Net Area Change<br />

1970. 1642 2557 912 166 -1993<br />

1980. 2375 1045 1201 779 -650<br />

1990s 1325 2261 332 -104 -1164<br />

..<br />

Note: I. Area If 10 ooO'ha<br />

Source: Computations based on the data obtained from CM1£, <strong>and</strong> Indian Agricultural<br />

Statistics (Various Issues)<br />

Importance <strong>of</strong> any <strong>of</strong> the individual components points to the static effect <strong>of</strong> it on<br />

the growth <strong>of</strong> output. The dynamic effect, i.e. interaction term indicates shifts in cropping<br />

pattern towards the crops which also experienced higher technological development. The<br />

results show that for the economy as a whole, the increased role <strong>of</strong> diversification was<br />

complemented by positive dynamic effects during the 19908. This indicates that the<br />

typology <strong>of</strong> the shift in the cropping pattern during the same period did not result in<br />

growth-depressing effect; it was other components <strong>of</strong> growth that adversely affected the<br />

growth <strong>of</strong> output. Among the regions, northern region alone has the distinction <strong>of</strong> being<br />

able to improve the crop pattern towards such crops that experienced better technological<br />

growth, through all the decades under review. In other words, most <strong>of</strong> the crops, which<br />

registered high growth in their yield relative to other crops, have improved their relative<br />

weight in the cropping pattern. The crops whose yield rates have gone down exhibit<br />

dedire in the proportion <strong>of</strong> gross cropped area under them.<br />

85


All other regions have shown mixed trends over a period <strong>of</strong> time. The eastern<br />

region has been able to achieve positive growth in productivity <strong>of</strong> crops towards which<br />

they have diversified during the 19908. This trend was absent during the previous two<br />

decades, when the dynamic effect was negative. Western <strong>and</strong> southern regions<br />

experienced high <strong>and</strong> negative dynamic effect during 19908, raising concerns about lack<br />

<strong>of</strong> technological improvement in the crops that contributed high to the cropping pattern.<br />

Ioterestingly, both these regions experienced positive dynamic effect during 1980s which<br />

turned negative subsequently. Though, there has been increased growth in the crop<br />

pattern shift towards high value crops during 1990s, the growth rate <strong>of</strong> these crops yield<br />

saw a dramatic decline during the same period, which resulted in the growth-depressing<br />

effect <strong>of</strong> diversification. This points out that diversification towards high value per se is<br />

not sufficient for increasing growth; it is also important that these crops remain<br />

remunerative over a period <strong>of</strong> time, through proper technological development, otherwise<br />

the gains from diversification will be meagre.<br />

To underst<strong>and</strong> the underlying factors that influenced the nature (static effect) <strong>and</strong><br />

direction (dynamic effect) <strong>of</strong> diversification in India, coefficient <strong>of</strong> correlation between<br />

several factors such as inputs development, market development, <strong>and</strong> socio-economic<br />

development have been computed. Correlation coefficients are measured separately for<br />

the static coefficient <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>of</strong> rice <strong>and</strong> wheat crop as one group, for non-food<br />

crops as another, <strong>and</strong> separately for dynamic coefficient <strong>of</strong>respective crop groups (table<br />

3.12).<br />

The coefficient correlation between the static coefficient <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>and</strong> input<br />

deVelopment shows that use <strong>of</strong> fertilizer <strong>and</strong> irrigation development are important for<br />

diversification towards rice <strong>and</strong> wheat. However, for non-food crops, it is irrigation that<br />

is important as many <strong>of</strong> these crops are highly water-intensive. Interestingly, the regions<br />

that have experienced high variability in rainfall over the last three decades could not<br />

diversifY towards non-food crops <strong>and</strong> this has adversely affected the growth <strong>of</strong> output in<br />

these regions. This illustrates that the variability in weather has influenced the process <strong>of</strong><br />

crop diversification <strong>and</strong> hence the growth <strong>of</strong> output in India. The availability <strong>of</strong> number<br />

<strong>of</strong> "


food crops but not on tbe diversification towards rice <strong>and</strong> wheat crops. This is expected<br />

as non-food crops are highly labour intensive compared to rice <strong>and</strong> wheat. The<br />

improvement in rural literacy is found important for tbe spread <strong>of</strong> non-food crops but not<br />

for food crops like rice <strong>and</strong> wheat. Development <strong>of</strong> markets exerted a positive influence<br />

on the diversification towards eitber <strong>of</strong> tbe crop groups (rice <strong>and</strong> wheat <strong>and</strong> non food<br />

crop) <strong>and</strong> making diversification growth inducive.<br />

Table 3.12: F actors In o uencinll N ature <strong>and</strong> Direction <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> III India<br />

Correlation coefficient Rice & Wheat Non-food crops Total<br />

Static (Area) Dynamic Static (Area) Dynamic Dynamic<br />

Fertilizer kglha 0.409 0.493 -0.158 0.251 00407<br />

Gross Irrigated Area 0.290 0.173 0.443 0.532 0.482<br />

Coefficient <strong>of</strong> variation 0334 0.351 -0.045 -0.128 -0.008<br />

<strong>of</strong> rainfall<br />

Total workers -0.127 -0.001 00471 0.287 0.216<br />

(Agricultural labourers<br />

<strong>and</strong> cultivators)<br />

Rural literacy rate 0.000 -0.124 0.445 -0.125 -0.033<br />

No. <strong>of</strong> regulated markets 0286 0.493 0.226 0.313 0.201<br />

Roads (in KIns.) -0.103 -0.266 0.319 0.125 00418<br />

Tractor (in Numbers) 0.609 0.609 0.120 -0.073 0.117<br />

Source: ComputatIOns based on the data obtamed from Central StatIstIcal Orgamzallon (Vanous Issues),<br />

CMIE, <strong>and</strong> Indian Agricultural Statistics (Various Issues), Fertilizer Statistics, Statistical Abstract India,<br />

Ghosh <strong>and</strong> Prabir, 2005, <strong>and</strong> Indian Labour Statistics (Various Issues)<br />

3.5. Summary<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> is one <strong>of</strong> components <strong>of</strong> output-growth besides area <strong>and</strong> crop<br />

productivity. There are several sub-components <strong>of</strong> diversification that influence growth<br />

in different ways. The components including diversity <strong>and</strong> spread in cropping pattern <strong>and</strong><br />

share <strong>of</strong> high value crops in GCA influence growth through their impact on income <strong>and</strong><br />

risk. Also, over-time, tbe relative role <strong>of</strong> all components <strong>of</strong> growth is expected to change<br />

due to changing policy, technology <strong>and</strong> external factors like economic liberalization <strong>and</strong><br />

international trade. Decline in agricultural growth during 1990s raises tbe need to identil'y<br />

the relative significance <strong>of</strong> components <strong>of</strong> growth in order to design appropriate<br />

agricultural policy to catalyse future growth in the sector.<br />

87


Initially, states were classified on the basis <strong>of</strong> different sub-components <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification. These different dimensions <strong>of</strong> diversification are analysed in the context<br />

<strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> output for the last three decades. The results indicate that at the state or<br />

regional level, there is a mixed picture regarding the typology <strong>of</strong> diversification. Some<br />

states exhibit high diversity in the cropping pattern but at the same time have less<br />

proportionate area under high value crops. There is also no direct link between diversity<br />

in cropping pattern with spread <strong>of</strong> crops. In regard to the relationship <strong>of</strong> different<br />

components <strong>of</strong> diversification with income <strong>and</strong> risk, income growth is higher in the states<br />

that have increased spread in the cropping pattern. These states have also shifted higher<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> area to non-food grains. However, this effect was perceptible only during the<br />

post-liberalization period in India. Until early I 990s, only the states which followed<br />

Green Revolution strategy were the major beneficiaries, but the effect has reduced during<br />

liberalization era as those regions performed relatively poor as compared to other states.<br />

Among the relative components <strong>of</strong> output growth in India, diversification has<br />

become an important source <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> output. This is again apparent in the postliberalization<br />

period. However, in the previous two decades, technological development<br />

was mainly responsible for output growth. Crop diversification has turned out to be a<br />

important component <strong>of</strong> growth in the southern <strong>and</strong> western regions, but this is attributed<br />

primarily to the negative net aggregate area change which in turn has increased the<br />

importance <strong>of</strong> crop substitution.<br />

The results <strong>of</strong> the dynamic effect indicate that northern region is the only one which<br />

through all the decades has been able to shift the crop pattern towards the crops that also<br />

experienced technological growth. Western <strong>and</strong> southern regions experienced high <strong>and</strong><br />

negative dynamic effect during the 19908, raising the concerns <strong>of</strong> the lack <strong>of</strong><br />

technological development in the crops that contributes significantly to the cropping<br />

pattern <strong>and</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> output <strong>of</strong> the region. It is clear now that diversification towards<br />

high value per se is not sufficient for increasing growth. It is important that these crops<br />

remain to be remunerative over a period <strong>of</strong> time through proper technological<br />

development; otherwise the gains from diversification will be meagre. For northern <strong>and</strong><br />

easter{! regions, it is more important to emphasis on increasing the crop diversification<br />

88


towards high value crops that include several non-food crops. These regions are highly<br />

vulnerable to external shocks due to specialisation in rice <strong>and</strong> wheat. For southern <strong>and</strong><br />

western regions, it is more important to improve the technology <strong>of</strong> many <strong>of</strong> the high<br />

value crops which are becoming crucial for the growth <strong>of</strong> the region.<br />

For improving the nature <strong>and</strong> direction <strong>of</strong> diversification in India, fertilizer <strong>and</strong><br />

irrigation development are important for catalysing shift <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern towards rice<br />

<strong>and</strong> wheat crops. However, for non-food crops, irrigation is important as many <strong>of</strong> these<br />

crops are highly water-intensive. High-labour intensity <strong>of</strong> these crops dem<strong>and</strong>s high<br />

density <strong>of</strong> workers. Finally, development <strong>of</strong> markets is vital in order to drive<br />

diversification towards either <strong>of</strong> the crop group (rice, wheat or non-food crops) <strong>and</strong> to<br />

improve the aggregate growth <strong>of</strong> agriculture sector in India.<br />

The results <strong>of</strong> this chapter indicate that the significance <strong>of</strong> diversification towards<br />

high value crops has increased over-time <strong>and</strong> it has turned out to be an important<br />

component <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> agricultural sector. In India, horticultural crops are high value<br />

crops not only in tenns <strong>of</strong> returns to l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> labour but also for their potential to provide<br />

higher level <strong>of</strong> employment in the sector. This calls for investigation <strong>of</strong> the trend in the<br />

growth <strong>of</strong> area <strong>and</strong> value <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops, the significance <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops in<br />

the study area i.e. <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>. Also, required is an examination <strong>of</strong> the economics<br />

<strong>of</strong> selected horticultural crops in the study area.<br />

89


Appen d" IX 31 L" CC<br />

" "<br />

1St 0 rops<br />

S.No Crop Name SNo Crop Name SNo Crop Name<br />

I Rice II Potato 21 Tea<br />

2 Wheat 12 Jute 22 C<strong>of</strong>fee<br />

3 Jowar 13 Ragi 23 Tobacco<br />

4 Bajra 14 Tur 24 Rubber<br />

5 Maize 15 Barley 25 Dry chillies<br />

6 Gram 16 Linseed 26 Black pepper<br />

7 Groundnut 17 Sesamum 27 Arecanut<br />

8 Rapseed & Mustard 18 Castor 28 Banana<br />

9 Sugar 19 Cocunut 29 Cashewnut<br />

10 Cotton 20 Mesta 30 Tapioca<br />

A ~ppen d" IX 32 Sh<br />

" : are 0 CRi cean dWh eat "G ID ross c roppe dA rea " ID I n dia<br />

Regions I TE 1972 I TE 1982 TE 1992 I TE 2002<br />

Nortbern Reejon<br />

Haryana 34.21 48.48 52.58 59.88<br />

Hi machal <strong>Pradesh</strong> 51.27 55.18 54.57 55.34<br />

Punjab 58.55 75.58 83.05 86.62<br />

Jammu <strong>and</strong> Kashmir 56.94 57.93 57.72 55.21<br />

Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong> 53.14 61.76 64.97 68.49<br />

Eastern Region<br />

Assam 77.27 74.20 75.11 74.58<br />

Bihar 68.86 70.11 71.16 74.43<br />

Orrisa 81.34 71.48 82.87 84.83<br />

West Bengal 83.86 80.02 79.76 76.58<br />

Western Ree:ion<br />

Gujarat 12.84 14.05 14.83 15.18<br />

Madhya <strong>Pradesh</strong> 38.77 40.53 43.79 45.58<br />

Maharashtra 15.54 15.24 14.01 14.87<br />

Rajasthan 16.06 16.71 16.73 16.77<br />

Sonthern region<br />

Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong> 35.25 36.19 35.92 32.43<br />

Kamataka 17.69 16.66 17.47 15.89<br />

Kerala 33.78 30.90 20.06 12.62<br />

Tamil Nadu 41.94 42.34 40.03 36.52<br />

Note .. The data consists 000 crops<br />

Source: CMIE, <strong>and</strong> . Indian Agricultural Statistics (Various Issues)<br />

90


Appen d' II 3.3 : C om pouo dG rowtb Rates <strong>of</strong> Area under Rice<br />

All<br />

Stales 1970s 1980s 1990s Decades<br />

Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong> 0.96 1.18 1.58 0.38<br />

Assam 0.95 0.73 0.44 0.72<br />

Haryana 8.16 2.50 5.09 4.59<br />

Kamataka -0.13 0.33 1.36 0.93<br />

Maharashtra 1.41 0.43 -0.42 0.29<br />

Rajasthan 3.16 -1.66 1.96 0.07<br />

West Bengal -0.55 1.62 0.21 0.58<br />

Bihar 1.48 1.42 2.20 -0.14<br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> 0.40 -0.86 -0.16 -0.66<br />

Kerala -1.32 -4.14 -5.90 -3.52<br />

Orrisa -1.56 0.63 0.02 0.04<br />

Tamil Nadu -0.05 -1.79 -0.54 -0.84<br />

Gujarat 4Jl6 0.04 1.14 1.32<br />

J&K 1.56 -0.23 -1.24 0.20<br />

Madhya <strong>Pradesh</strong> 1.34 -0.15 2.03 0.51<br />

Punjab 12.50 4.37 2.49 5.67<br />

Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong> 2.26 0.46 1.85 1.00<br />

Source: CMIE, <strong>and</strong> Indian Agncu1tuTaI StatIStICS (Vanous Issues)<br />

Appendii 3. 4: Compound Growtb Rates <strong>of</strong> Area uode rWbeat<br />

All<br />

States 1970s 1980s 1990. Decades<br />

Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong> -3.92 -8.40 3.71 -2.79<br />

Assam 10.08 -3.68 -0.63 1.09<br />

Haryana 3.75 0.80 2.28 2.32<br />

Kamataka ·0.58 -6.22 1.95 -1.86<br />

Maharashtra 2.39 -4.35 2.17 -1.34<br />

Rajasthan 1.58 -1.77 1.55 1.43<br />

West Bengal -2.61 -1.38 4.58 -0.55<br />

Bihar 0.78 1.79 0.82 1.00<br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> 1.79 0.25 -0.04 0.70<br />

Kerala NA NA NA NA<br />

Orrisa ·1.56 0.63 0.02 0.04<br />

Tamil Nodu NA NA NA NA<br />

Gujarat 3.34 -2.31 -4.40 -0.59<br />

J&K 0.91 1.60 0.83 1.28<br />

Madhya <strong>Pradesh</strong> 0.41 0.33 0.37 1.08<br />

Puniab 2.99 0.68 0.43 1.29<br />

Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong> 3.98 0.45 1.02 1.65<br />

Note. (I). NA IS not apphcable.<br />

Source: CMIE, <strong>and</strong> Indian Agricultural Statistics (Various Issues)<br />

91


Appen dix3.5 : C ompound Growth Rates <strong>of</strong> Area under Non-Food <strong>Crops</strong><br />

All<br />

States I 970s 1980s 1990s Decades<br />

Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong> -0.74 4.43 -0.34 2.28<br />

Assam 1.77 1.36 1.28 1.59<br />

Haryana 3.96 4.27 0.08 3.17<br />

Kamatak. 0.72 3.30 -0.96 1.86<br />

Maharashtra 2.19 0.98 0.59 1.13<br />

Raiasthan 2.24 3.91 1.38 3.18<br />

West Bengal 4.31 3.91 5.29 3.27<br />

Bihar 0.16 3.08 -2.36 1.90<br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> 2.14 7.47 3.98 6.95<br />

Kerala -0.26 1.87 -0.57 0.65<br />

Orrisa 7.74 2.41 -1.39 1.15<br />

TamilNadu -1.17 4.09 -2.54 0.62<br />

Gujarat 2.69 -1.29 1.55 0.81<br />

J&K 4.29 7.43 -1.65 5.32<br />

Madhya <strong>Pradesh</strong> -0.62 7.69 2.13 4.60<br />

Punjab -0.86 1.09 -2.41 -0.30<br />

Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong> 1.43 1.30 0.53 1.64<br />

Source. CMIE, <strong>and</strong> indIan Agncultural StatistICS (Vanous Issues)<br />

Appendix 3_6: Gross Value <strong>of</strong> Output <strong>of</strong> States in India @J993-94 prices<br />

TE 1972 TE 1982 TE 1992 TE2002<br />

Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong> 596344 854018 1151967 1380645<br />

Assam 232988 291762 368852 432583<br />

Bibar 485038 487862 610484 701505<br />

Gujarat 547764 771741 753674 759615<br />

Haryana 288122 374300 606125 730574<br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> 41808 44192 59196 61288<br />

Jammu & Kashmir 52613 74273 76686 70728<br />

Karnataka 491105 590095 827505 1139481<br />

Kerala 448102 398119 485199 583693<br />

Madhya <strong>Pradesh</strong> 590515 672096 930210 883386<br />

Maharashlra 462352 837740 1015724 1328372<br />

Orrisa 265296 308074 422560 356616<br />

Punjab 426688 679359 1018558 1190417<br />

Rajasthan 401725 469204 766035 791150<br />

Tamil Nadu 585907 567287 897779 1069361<br />

Vttar <strong>Pradesh</strong> 1314870 1712200 2292292 2687352<br />

West Belll1.al 467249 495091 871970 1130809<br />

India 7739386 9675553 13302690 15770206<br />

lfOlc:<br />

j. Figures are in Rs. Lakhs<br />

Source: Central Statistical Organization, Various Issues.<br />

92


Appendix 3.7: Distribution <strong>of</strong> States by Trend towards Spread or Concentration in<br />

C .<br />

nlppinl Pattern<br />

1'170. 1980s . 1990s All Decad ..<br />

Group <strong>of</strong> States TamilNadu, Haryana, Kerala, Madhya <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Rajasthan. Kerala,<br />

showing no chauge Kamataka, Andhra Jammu & <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Jammu & Kashmir<br />

in Conceutration <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Kashmir, Andhra Jammu & Kashmir,<br />

ludex<br />

Mabarashtra, <strong>Pradesh</strong> Assam<br />

Raiasthan<br />

Group <strong>of</strong> States Kerala, Jammu & Rajasthan, Kamataka, Tamil Clujarat, Karnataka,<br />

showing increase Kashmir, Gujarat, Gujarat, Nadu, Maharashtra Assam, Andhra<br />

in spread <strong>of</strong> West Bengal, Karnataka, Tamil Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong>, <strong>Pradesh</strong>,<br />

cropping pattern<br />

Assam, Orrisa Nadu, West Bengal Maharashtra, Tamil<br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> Mabarashtra N adu, West Bengal<br />

Group <strong>of</strong> States Punjab, Uttar Punjab, Uttar Orrisa, Haryana, Punjab, Uttar<br />

sbowing increase <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Bihar, <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Bihar, Rajasthan, Punjab, <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Bihar"<br />

in Concentration Haryana, Madhya Orrisa, Assam, Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Bihar, Haryana, <strong>Himachal</strong><br />

<strong>Pradesh</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong> cropping<br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> Clujamt, Kerala <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Orrisa,<br />

<strong>Pradesh</strong>, West<br />

Madhya <strong>Pradesh</strong><br />

pattern<br />

Bengal, Madhya<br />

<strong>Pradesh</strong><br />

Source. CMIE, <strong>and</strong> Indian Agncultural StattslIcs (Vanous Issues)<br />

Appendix 3.8: Distribution <strong>of</strong> States by Trend in Shift <strong>of</strong> Cropping Pattern towards<br />

N on-F 00 de rill's<br />

1'170. 19800 1990s All Decad ..<br />

Group <strong>of</strong> States Punjab, Madhya Orrisa, Punjab, Rajasthan, Punjab, Punjab, Madhya<br />

reducing Sbare <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Assam, Karnataka, Madhya <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Kamataka,<br />

<strong>of</strong> area under Kamataka, Maharashtra, <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Andhra Orrisa, <strong>Himachal</strong><br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Orrisa, <strong>Pradesh</strong><br />

non-food crops<br />

<strong>Pradesh</strong><br />

Bihar, <strong>Himachal</strong><br />

<strong>Pradesh</strong>, Haryana<br />

Group <strong>of</strong> States Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Jammu & Jammu & Kashmir, Bihar, Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong>,<br />

sbowing no Bihar, Jammu & Kashmir, Bihar, Tamil Nadu, Assam, Jammu & Kashmir,<br />

change in Sbare Kashmir, Gujamt, Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong> Assam<br />

Tamil Nadu, West Bengal,<br />

<strong>of</strong> area uuder<br />

Mabarashtra, Madhya <strong>Pradesh</strong>,<br />

non-food crops<br />

Kamataka<br />

Group <strong>of</strong> States Haryana, Kerala, Gujarat, Maharashtra, West Mabarashtra, West<br />

increaSing Sbare Assam, Rajasthan, Haryana, Tamil Bengal, Gujarat, Bengal, Rajasthan,<br />

<strong>of</strong> area under<br />

nOD-food crops<br />

West Bengal, Nadu, Rajasthan, Kerala Tamil Nadu,<br />

Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Kerala, Andhra Haryana, Gujarat,<br />

Orrisa <strong>Pradesh</strong> Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong>,<br />

Kerala<br />

Source. CMIE, <strong>and</strong> indIan Agncultural StatIstIcs (Vanous Issues)<br />

93


CHAPTERN<br />

DNERSIFICATION AND HORTICULTURAL<br />

CROPS: A CASE OF HIMACHAL PRADESH<br />

4.1 Introduction<br />

There are many facets <strong>of</strong> diversification but it is necessary to emphasise on<br />

diversification towards high value crops as its major proxy. Among the high value crops<br />

grown in India, horticultura1 crops emerge as the representative <strong>and</strong> also an interesting<br />

case-study <strong>of</strong> diversification in Indian agriculture. Therefore, an overview <strong>of</strong> horticultura1<br />

sector <strong>and</strong> its growth in India over a period <strong>of</strong> time is mapped. Not only the past<br />

performance, but also the future prospects <strong>of</strong> the horticultural sector are bright. This is<br />

mainly because consumption pattern <strong>of</strong> people has been shifting towards horticultura1<br />

crops. Rjsing per capita income, growing urbanization <strong>and</strong> liberalization <strong>of</strong> the economy<br />

have led to increase in dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> exports <strong>of</strong> these crops. It is here one need to find the<br />

significance <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops in the agricultural sector. <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> (HP)<br />

presents an interesting case in diversification towards horticultural crops in India. In this<br />

study, the significance <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops in the agricultural sector <strong>of</strong> HP <strong>and</strong> income<br />

<strong>and</strong> risk patterns <strong>of</strong> the selected horticultural crops are analysed. To begin with, the trend<br />

in the growth <strong>of</strong> horticultural sector <strong>and</strong> its relevance in the agriCUltural sector are<br />

examined. We then provide details <strong>of</strong> the selected villages <strong>and</strong> the socio-economic<br />

features <strong>of</strong> the selected farmers. Income <strong>and</strong> risk patterns <strong>of</strong> the farmers producing<br />

selected horticultural crops have been worked out. This is complemented by estimation <strong>of</strong><br />

labour dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> output supply elasticities <strong>of</strong> the cauliflower producers by using a<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>it function approach. Impact <strong>of</strong> extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation to horticultural crops across<br />

different farm sizes on income <strong>and</strong> risk is also assessed.<br />

94


4.2 <strong>Horticultural</strong> Sector in India<br />

Fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables form the single largest sub-sector <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops in<br />

India, accounting for 63.8% <strong>of</strong> the area <strong>and</strong> more than 80% <strong>of</strong> the total production.<br />

(National Horticultura\ Board, 2009). India is the world's second largest producer <strong>of</strong><br />

fruits & vegetables contributing to \0% <strong>and</strong> 14.4% respectively <strong>of</strong> the total world<br />

production. India is the largest producer <strong>of</strong> banana, mango, sapotas <strong>and</strong> acid limes <strong>and</strong><br />

enjoys reputation for highest productivity in grapes, sapota <strong>and</strong> banana. In vegetables,<br />

India occupies prime position in the production <strong>of</strong> cauliflower <strong>and</strong> pea; second in onion;<br />

cabbage, tomato <strong>and</strong> brinjal, <strong>and</strong> third in cabbage in the world (Singh et a1. 2004).<br />

Over the last five decades, there has been a three-fold increase in area under fruits<br />

<strong>and</strong> four-fold increase in its production. It is estimated that since 1961, area, production<br />

<strong>and</strong> productivity <strong>of</strong> fruits increased by 3, 6.2, <strong>and</strong> 2 times respectively. Vegetable<br />

production has tripled in the last 50 years. The total production <strong>of</strong> vegetables has<br />

increased from 40.08 MT in 1980 to 90.35 MT 2000 registering a growth rate <strong>of</strong> 4.92%<br />

per year. The value output from fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables demonstrated a growth rate <strong>of</strong><br />

5.76% per annum between 1960-61 <strong>and</strong> 1992-93 in real terms. Historically, there was<br />

virtually no export <strong>of</strong> fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables. The exports <strong>of</strong> these crops have picked up<br />

remarkably .after 1980s. Exports <strong>of</strong> fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables more than doubled during the<br />

last two decades. The value <strong>of</strong> horticultura\ exports from India increased from 487 crores<br />

in 1991-92 to 2394 in 2002-03. During the same period, the annual growth rate in<br />

horticultural export is measured at 12% in quantity <strong>and</strong> 34% in value. It is important to<br />

note that although India is ranked second in the world production <strong>of</strong> fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables,<br />

per capita availability <strong>of</strong> fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables in India still continues to be much below<br />

dietary requirements (Singh et al. 2(04).<br />

95


4.2.1. State-wise Pattern <strong>of</strong> Development <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong><br />

Sector<br />

There are three prime indices by which the importance <strong>of</strong> horticultural sector <strong>and</strong> its<br />

trend can be quantified. One measure is the trend in the compound growth rate in area<br />

under the horticultural crops. The contribution <strong>of</strong> the horticulture to the total output<br />

produced in the agricultural sector <strong>and</strong> location quotients provide the details about<br />

relative significance <strong>of</strong> the sector in agriculture at any given point <strong>of</strong> time.<br />

Growth rates <strong>of</strong> area under horticultural crops in the regions where horticultural<br />

crops are <strong>of</strong> high significance indicate that only <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> (HP) <strong>and</strong> West Bengal<br />

could demonstrate higher growth (figure 4.1). Bihar, Jammu & Kashmir (J&K), Tamil<br />

Nadu, Assam <strong>and</strong> Orrisa have registered either negative or stagnant growth in area under<br />

horticultural crops. These states have experienced positive growth in area under fruits but<br />

they have shown dramatic decline in the area under vegetable crops. This may be because<br />

<strong>of</strong> lack <strong>of</strong> adequate irrigation facilities in these states as vegetables are relatively more<br />

water-intensive crops <strong>and</strong> fruits are capital intensive. There are several states, where<br />

horticultural crops cover insignificant amount <strong>of</strong> area in the gross cropped area. Some <strong>of</strong><br />

these states Le., Maharashtra, Karnataka, <strong>and</strong> Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong> are now experiencing<br />

higher growth in area under horticultural crops enhancing the significance <strong>of</strong> horticultural<br />

crops in the GCA. States like Gujarat, Rajasthan <strong>and</strong> Haryana have demonstrated higher<br />

growth rates in area under horticultural crops, but still horticultural crops cover<br />

insignificant area <strong>of</strong> the gross cropped area in these states.<br />

96


Figure 4.1 :Compound Growth Rate In Area under <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> In India<br />

14.00,--------------------------------------------------------------------<br />

12.00 +1------------------------------------<br />

10.00 +-1 --------------------------------<br />

-<br />

~<br />

8.00 I ----I<br />

~<br />

i<br />

t<br />

6.00 f-------<br />

4.00 +-<br />

~ I ~ I L<br />

I ::: ·llJlll· ... ~.<br />

.l<br />

··.-1970S<br />

~<br />

.1980.<br />

[] 19905<br />

--------<br />

I 400 II<br />

, .~..


Since value <strong>of</strong> crops is an important indicator for underst<strong>and</strong>ing the relevance <strong>of</strong><br />

crops in the agricultural sector, the contribution <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops to the total value <strong>of</strong><br />

agricultural output is computed for all states for the last two decades. The results are<br />

presented in table 4.1. Some <strong>of</strong> the highly specialized zones or marginal regions in India<br />

have highest dependence on horticultural sector for their agricultural output <strong>and</strong> growth.<br />

Many eastern states fall under this category viz; Assam, Orissa, <strong>and</strong> West Bengal among<br />

others. For HP <strong>and</strong> J&K, the contribution <strong>of</strong> horticultural sector to the gross output<br />

generated in the cropping sector (minus livestock sector) is around 47% <strong>and</strong> it ranges<br />

between 30-32% if livestock sector is included. However, with or without taking<br />

livestock sector into account, these states continue to have the highest contributions from<br />

horticultural crops to total value <strong>of</strong> gross output in the agricultural sector. Among other<br />

regions, Kamataka, Maharashtra <strong>and</strong> Tamil Nadu show moderate level <strong>of</strong> significance for<br />

these crops in the total value <strong>of</strong> their agricultural output <strong>and</strong> this trend has been<br />

increasing significantly over a period <strong>of</strong> time.<br />

Table 4.1: Share <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> in the Total Value <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Ou~ut in India<br />

States TE 1982 TE 1992 TE 2002<br />

I Rajasthan 1.52 2.89 4.12<br />

Punjab 4.52 5.21 7.08<br />

Haryana 5.15 4.49 9.95<br />

: Madh~a Pradesb 6.45 6.69 12.11<br />

Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong> 11.56 11.11 15.05<br />

Andbra <strong>Pradesh</strong> 8.83 11.39 15.76<br />

Gujarat 8.27 10.55 18.58<br />

Kerala 21.33 32.35 27.00<br />

~i1Nadu 9.83 19.82 27.53<br />

Karnataka 5.34 25.14 28.68<br />

Mabarasbtra 7.36 24.32 30.61<br />

i Assam 17.51 26.95 31.40<br />

, West Bengal 20.54 28.00 38.99<br />

Orrisa 18.21 28.01 42.50<br />

l.!Jibar 29.84 31.92 45.15<br />

I Himacbal <strong>Pradesh</strong> 17.89 32.52 47.43<br />

Jammu & Kashmir 17.86 34.04 48.31<br />

Note.<br />

i. Figures are in percentage<br />

Source: National Account Statistics (Various Issues)<br />

98


Location quotient is used as a measure to find the relative significance <strong>of</strong><br />

horticultural crops across states. The higher the value <strong>of</strong> location quotient, the greater is<br />

the concentration <strong>of</strong> the selected sector in that state. The results show that these crops are<br />

highly concentrated in J&K, <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>, West Bengal, Assam, Orrisa <strong>and</strong> Bihar<br />

(figure 42). These are the states which are relatively less developed in terms <strong>of</strong> irrigation<br />

<strong>and</strong> modern technology. KeraIa, where horticultural sector was <strong>of</strong> great significant in the<br />

agricultural sector (indicated by the location quotient coefficient for the Triennium<br />

Ending (TE) 1972 period), experienced a dramatic fall in its relevance over a period <strong>of</strong><br />

time. Some states like Karnataka <strong>and</strong> Haryana have been showing higher growth in<br />

horticultural crops. However, they are among the states where this sector is yet not a<br />

major contributor to the agricultural sector. The value <strong>of</strong> location quotient is less than one<br />

in their case. <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> is one <strong>of</strong> the few states, which has demonstrated high<br />

value <strong>of</strong> location quotient, huge contribution from horticultural sector to the aggregate<br />

output <strong>of</strong> the agricultural sector <strong>and</strong> that experienced moderate to high growth in area<br />

under horticultural crops in the last three decades.<br />

99


---~ -<br />

figure 4.2: Location Quotient <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> In India<br />

10<br />

9<br />

8<br />

-<br />

I e<br />

5<br />

j<br />

!


4.3. <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong>: A <strong>Case</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong><br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> towards horticultural crops is acknowledged as an alluring option,<br />

but where such diversification be more induced in the country like India, which is highly<br />

diverse in its climatic features, is a question <strong>of</strong> great interest among the policy makers.<br />

Should all states move towards diversifying their production pattern? This may have<br />

serious consequences for food security in India, as it is found that there has been an<br />

increase in substitution effects besides technological fatigue in major food grains. It is<br />

vital to follow an agro-c1imatic approach by identifying the relative comparative<br />

advantages <strong>of</strong> states in specific crops in order to decide the direction <strong>and</strong> regions for<br />

diversification. The second concern is about the regional dimension. <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

towards horticultural crops requires better market <strong>and</strong> infrastructure facilities <strong>and</strong> at the<br />

same time, government expenditure on infrastructure <strong>and</strong> public investment has been<br />

declining continuously over the years (Ch<strong>and</strong>, 2005). The moot question is whether<br />

backward regions with relative comparative advantages in some horticultural crops can<br />

realize any growth in diversification? What follows is an appraisal <strong>of</strong> this complex issue.<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> means to induce spreading <strong>of</strong> crops given the diversity in the agroecological<br />

zones. In other words, cropping pattern is dictated more by comparative<br />

advantage. India presents a picture <strong>of</strong> great diversity in geography <strong>and</strong> agro-climatic<br />

zones, some <strong>of</strong> which are less conducive to cereals <strong>and</strong> more conducive to non-cereals.<br />

Yet, the over-emphasis on promoting food-grains through support, subsidy <strong>and</strong> research<br />

inputs have resulted in the domination <strong>of</strong> cereals at the cost <strong>of</strong> other crops 18. There are<br />

instances <strong>of</strong> states like <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> (HP), where agriculture is still dominated by<br />

food grains despite distinct comparative advantage for horticultural crops, in terms <strong>of</strong> its<br />

agro-climatic conditions. Such non agro-ecological approach at the national <strong>and</strong> regional<br />

level have spawned many problems, including creating dualism in agriculture in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

backward <strong>and</strong> progressive regions.<br />

" PresenIl y 66% <strong>of</strong> GCA under food grains<br />

101


The unresolved question is whether diversification can be a panacea; if so will it<br />

solve the problem <strong>of</strong> regional disparity. Given this challenge, can India hope to address<br />

the problem <strong>of</strong> regional disparity through diversification, which, by definition, requires<br />

better infrastructure, better access to markets etc., all <strong>of</strong> which calls for enormous state<br />

funding. There is a fear that marginal regions will further get marginalized <strong>and</strong> may not<br />

participate, despite having better potential for diversification. Indian government is<br />

increasingly providing higher subsidies to food grains while its expenditure on<br />

infrastructure has shown dramatic decline, which contradicts the government claims <strong>of</strong><br />

funding infrastructure to improve diversification <strong>and</strong> achieve better growth <strong>and</strong> regional<br />

development. The issue is whether the low pr<strong>of</strong>ile states with higher potential for<br />

producing horticultural crops can participate in the quest for earning better income <strong>and</strong><br />

growth. It is feared that the regions with high growth in the past might surpass the weaker<br />

states in diversification <strong>and</strong> further accentuate the problem <strong>of</strong> regional disparities <strong>and</strong><br />

growth in India.<br />

The major concern is about emphasising diversification in states, which have<br />

inherent advantages in production <strong>of</strong> non-cereal crops, but are precluded to produce so<br />

mainly due to irrational policies <strong>of</strong> the government. <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> is one <strong>of</strong> the best<br />

example, as agro-dimatic wise it is endowed with potential <strong>of</strong> growing wide range <strong>of</strong><br />

fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables, but is still dominated by food crops. This region has enormous<br />

potential <strong>and</strong> comparative advantage in production <strong>of</strong> fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables that have high<br />

domestic <strong>and</strong> international dem<strong>and</strong>. There is need to encourage diversification in HP.<br />

4.4. Significance <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong><br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> is a mountainous state with very wide climate diversity ranging<br />

from sub-tropical to temperate regions. In total, there are four different agro-c1imatic<br />

zones in the state (figure 4.3). <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> has all the climatic attributes to produce<br />

wide range <strong>of</strong> crops, ranging from food grains, horticulture to medicinal, herbs <strong>and</strong><br />

flrcu.lture. <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> is called the horticultural state <strong>of</strong>.lnd~ due to its<br />

potenllal for producing most <strong>of</strong> the horticultural crops grown In India. Wide range <strong>of</strong><br />

102


fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables are grown in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> that includes around 25 types <strong>of</strong><br />

frui ts <strong>and</strong> roughly all vegetables that are produced in other parts <strong>of</strong> the country.<br />

Figure 4.3: Agro-Climatic Zones in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong><br />

.--._-<br />

--- _<br />

--<br />

......... -,--<br />

Zone 1 Zone 2 Zone 3 Zone 4<br />

Low-hill<br />

EcololZV ubtrooical Mid hill sub-humid Hildt hill temoerate wet Hildt hill tempeJllte dry<br />

Geographic area (in %) 35 32 25 8<br />

rroooed area (in %) 33 53 11 3<br />

Irrigated area (in %) 17 18 8 5<br />

~itude (MASL*) Uoto 914 915-4523 1524-2472 2476-7000<br />

Rainfall (cm) 100-150 \50-300 100-200 20-50<br />

Note.<br />

i. MASL is mean above Sea Level<br />

Source: Directorate <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, Shiml&, lIP<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>of</strong> agriculture towards selective horticultural crops is compatible<br />

with the comparative advantage <strong>of</strong> the region (Sharma, 2005). Table 4.2 indicates that net<br />

returns from production <strong>of</strong> different fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables are relatively higher than<br />

returns from other crops produced in the state. The state has seasonal, quality <strong>and</strong> cost<br />

advantage in production <strong>of</strong> a variety <strong>of</strong> fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables <strong>and</strong> adoption <strong>of</strong> horticulture<br />

crpps is advantageous to <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> economy in several ways. First, it promotes<br />

the productive use <strong>of</strong> abundant marginal l<strong>and</strong>s available in the region. Second, these<br />

crops help in maintaining <strong>and</strong> improving the ecology <strong>and</strong> environment by promoting soil<br />

103


conservation <strong>and</strong> improving soil fertility. In economic terms, it can lead to significant<br />

improvement in the income <strong>and</strong> employment <strong>and</strong> quality <strong>of</strong> Iiftl <strong>of</strong> the people (Sharma et<br />

aI, 2003). A comparison <strong>of</strong> productivity <strong>of</strong> major crops in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> with that <strong>of</strong><br />

all India shows that the productivity <strong>of</strong> many <strong>of</strong> the horticultural crops in <strong>Himachal</strong><br />

<strong>Pradesh</strong> is higher than all-India average (table 4.3).<br />

Table 4.2: N et R etums f rom V' anous C rops In 'Hi machal Pradesb, 2001<br />

Cate20rv <strong>Crops</strong> I Net returns (Rslha)<br />

Cereals<br />

Wheal 2259<br />

Maize 1715<br />

Barley 901<br />

Paddy 1120<br />

V02etables<br />

Tomato 32989<br />

Capsicum 18493<br />

Peas 10706<br />

Cauliflower 33691<br />

Cabbage 10811<br />

Beans 3136<br />

OtbercroDS<br />

I Potato I 5058<br />

I Ginger I 31939<br />

Plantation Cro,,"<br />

Apple 26900<br />

Citrus 9400<br />

Plum 6570<br />

Peach 6340<br />

Apricot 12650<br />

Pear 3810<br />

Source: Sharma, et aI. 2003<br />

Table 4.3: Productivity <strong>of</strong> Major <strong>Crops</strong> in Himacbal Pradesb <strong>and</strong> India, 2001<br />

(Rs.lba)<br />

CroDs <strong>Himachal</strong> Prodesb India<br />

Rice 1423 2914<br />

!wheat 1266 2756<br />

Maize 2272 1769<br />

~omato 34645 15068<br />

Beans (ereen) 9921 9600<br />

Pea (2reen) 9574 10000<br />

Cabbage 28663 18085<br />

k:auliOower 18164 15000<br />

~icum<br />

9355 9074<br />

tato 23890 18657<br />

Source. Shanna, et 01. 2003<br />

104


The relevance <strong>of</strong> any crop or crop-group in the agricultural sector <strong>of</strong> the economy<br />

can be gauged from the relative growth in th~ir area <strong>and</strong> value <strong>of</strong> output. The comparison<br />

<strong>of</strong> horticultura1 sector crops with non-horticultural crops in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> shows that<br />

horticultura1 crops are an important source for the growth <strong>of</strong> agriculture. The growth <strong>of</strong><br />

area <strong>and</strong> value <strong>of</strong> output <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops is relatively high as compared to nonhorticultura1<br />

crops (table 4.4). This signifies the growth in the technology (productivity)<br />

<strong>and</strong> market (prices) <strong>of</strong> crops within horticultura1 sector. Since there is enonnous<br />

difference in the rate <strong>of</strong> growth in the value <strong>of</strong> output <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops as compared<br />

to other crops, this can result in significant increase in the contribution <strong>of</strong> horticultural<br />

sector to the overall growth in the agricultural sector over a period <strong>of</strong> time as is evidenced<br />

by the fact that the share <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops in the total value <strong>of</strong> output generated in<br />

agriCUlture increased significantly from 24 % in TE 1982 to 47% in TE 2002 (table 4.5).<br />

Ta ble 4.4: Growth Rate in Area <strong>and</strong> Value <strong>of</strong> Output <strong>of</strong> Major Crop Groups in UP<br />

19705 19805 19905<br />

Area Value Area Value Area Value<br />

Non-horticultural <strong>Crops</strong> 0.88 0.96 0.23 1.47 -0.41 0.75<br />

<strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> 4.12 7.25 4.72 5.47 3.60 5.90<br />

Total 1.03 1.74 0.51 2.20 -0.55 3.33<br />

Source: NatIOnal Account Statistics, Annual Season <strong>and</strong> Crop report <strong>and</strong> Directorate <strong>of</strong> HortIculture<br />

(Various Issues)<br />

Table 4.5: Sh fC rop roups ID ross VI a ueo f 0 urpu t t' ID A 19ncu • ltu re ID • HP<br />

TE 1982 TE 2002<br />

Total Cereals 60 40<br />

<strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> (F&V) 24 47<br />

Others Crop Groups 16 13<br />

Note:<br />

i. Figures are in Percentage<br />

Source: National Account Statistics (Various Issues)<br />

are 0 G 'G<br />

Broadly, there are four different agro-c1imatic zones in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>. The<br />

geographical area <strong>and</strong> agro-climatic features <strong>of</strong> the districts in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> are<br />

quite diverse which explains, partially the difference in the pattern <strong>of</strong> crop mix across<br />

districts. The regional pattern <strong>of</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> growth in area under different crops indicates that<br />

arta under fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables has grown at a faster rate in all the districts <strong>of</strong> <strong>Himachal</strong><br />

<strong>Pradesh</strong>, with few exceptions (table 4.6). Wheat <strong>and</strong> maize, which dominated the<br />

\05


cropping pattern in early 19708, did not experience significant growth in area. Further,<br />

area under few other hi&!! value crops, like rice <strong>and</strong> oil seeds declined during the same<br />

period. Apple is the most prominent horticultural crop in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>. The district<br />

level pattern demonstrates that major growth <strong>of</strong> area under apple has taken place in<br />

Shimla, Chamba, Kinnaur <strong>and</strong> Lahaul & Spiti (L&S). Though, all the districts have<br />

shown higher rate <strong>of</strong> growth in the area under fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables than any other crop,<br />

only few districts have significant proportion <strong>of</strong> area in their gross cropped area under<br />

these crop groups.<br />

a e . . ompoun d G ro wth Rat<br />

esm . A rea 0 fM' alor C rops In . D' Ishicts 0 fHP<br />

T bl 46 C<br />

Districts Rice Maize Wheat Barley Millets Pulses Oilseeds Potato Voget Apple<br />

I<br />

abies<br />

. Bilaspur -3.\3 0.83 1.08 -0.53 NI ·9.95 ·1.98 -0.28 3.44 NI<br />

: Chamba -0.43 0.21 0.78 -2.12 -2.55 ·0.03 0.25 1.28 1.35 13.75<br />

Hamirpur -3.11 0.84 0.66 -0.60 NI -13.10 -3.00 0.27 -0.64 NI<br />

Kangra 0.04 0.82 0.60 -2.26 NI -3.50 -1.76 2.81 2.20 NI<br />

, Kinnaur NI 0.37 -5.51 -2.35 -3.39 6.64 NI -2.92 1.60 8.29<br />

i KulJu -2.49 1.07 1.17 -2.42 -6.04 0.21 1.75 0.38 2.64 5.36<br />

, L&S NI 3.76 4.46 -2.70 -3.53 9.42 0.69 0.35 0.34 NI<br />

M<strong>and</strong>i -0.90 2.27 0.61 -1.17 -0.98 -2.14 0.98 0.61 3.41 -2.65<br />

Shimla -2.84 -1.10 -2.12 -2.39 ·2.61 0.90 4.46 -1.45 2.02 5.54<br />

, Sirrnour 0.28 0.04 0.13 -1.25 -0.88 -0.59 0.36 2.60 5.12 -0.27<br />

. Solan -1.03 0.01 0.58 0.20 NI 4.80 -1.78 -2.40 4.80 NI<br />

Una 0.22 2.00 1.10 NI NI ·9.79 2.14 6.87 3.56 NI<br />

Nt crop IS not lmportant for the dlstnct<br />

Source: Annual Season <strong>and</strong> Crop Report, various issues<br />

Fruits<br />

6.90<br />

5.67<br />

6.43<br />

7.40<br />

6.50<br />

5.75<br />

NI<br />

1.87<br />

5.66<br />

1.18<br />

0.45<br />

6.65<br />

The distribution <strong>of</strong> value <strong>of</strong> output, productivity <strong>and</strong> its growth over a period shows<br />

that the districts, that experienced higher rate <strong>of</strong> growth in area under horticultural crops<br />

have achieved relatively high growth in the value <strong>of</strong> aggregate output <strong>and</strong> productivity<br />

(table 4.7). Shirnla, KuJlu <strong>and</strong> Labaul <strong>and</strong> Spiti experienced a compound growth <strong>of</strong> 7.76<br />

%,9.54 % <strong>and</strong> 9.89 % respectively in value <strong>of</strong> output <strong>and</strong> compound growth <strong>of</strong> 8.85 %,<br />

7.17 % <strong>and</strong> 8.65 % respectively in productivity levels. In districts, where horticultural<br />

production is low due to them having lower acreage under the crops, the rate <strong>of</strong> growth in<br />

output <strong>and</strong> productivity is either stagnant or negative. Bilaspur <strong>and</strong> Una are the two<br />

districts, where the allocation <strong>of</strong> area under the horticultural crops is minimal <strong>and</strong> the<br />

~wth rate <strong>of</strong> output in these regions st<strong>and</strong>s at -0.02 <strong>and</strong> 0.15 respectively. The growth<br />

rale in aggregate l<strong>and</strong> productivity ill these regions has been only -0.23 <strong>and</strong> -0.06<br />

respectively from 1972 to 200 I.<br />

106


Table 4.7: Value <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Output <strong>and</strong> Productivity in Districts <strong>of</strong>HP<br />

i Districts Value <strong>of</strong> Value <strong>of</strong> Growth rate in Total Value <strong>of</strong> Total Value <strong>of</strong> Growth rate in<br />

-<br />

! output (IE output (IE value <strong>of</strong> output Productivity Productivity productivity<br />

1974) 2001) 1972-2001 . (TE 1974) (TE2001) 1972-2001<br />

I<br />

,<br />

4869 4846<br />

, Bilasl)llr<br />

-0.02 8852<br />

8502 -0.23<br />

I Chamba<br />

5030 8554 2.69 8\13 13160<br />

2.39<br />

• Harnirpur<br />

4929 5328 0.31 6846 76\1<br />

0.43<br />

Kangra<br />

19204 27079 1.58 %50<br />

12365<br />

1.08<br />

,<br />

Kinnaur<br />

896 2764 8.01 8150 307\1<br />

10.56<br />

, Kullu 5800 20192 9.54 \1373 32568<br />

7.17<br />

i Lahaul & Spiti<br />

583 2084 9.89 19444 63152<br />

8.65<br />

, M<strong>and</strong>i<br />

12851 18045 1.55 8802<br />

11421<br />

1.14<br />

. Shiml.<br />

12449 37583 7.76 \1857 39149<br />

8.85<br />

,<br />

~Sinnour<br />

6889 12959 3.39 9064<br />

17051<br />

3.39<br />

lSolan<br />

6629 12154 3.21 9470<br />

18991<br />

3.87<br />

I Una<br />

5813 6041 0.15 8676<br />

8630<br />

-0.06<br />

I <strong>Himachal</strong><br />

l<strong>Pradesh</strong><br />

85944 157629 3.21 9372<br />

16605<br />

2.97<br />

Note.<br />

I, The value <strong>of</strong> output <strong>and</strong> productivity are @ 1993-94 prices (in Rs.)<br />

Source: Annual Season <strong>and</strong> Crop report (Various Issues)<br />

To examine the effect <strong>of</strong> fluctuating proportionate area under fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables<br />

<strong>and</strong> consequent change in level <strong>of</strong> productivity, regression method is used. It is<br />

hypothesized that productivity levels (value <strong>of</strong> output per ha) in a region is a function <strong>of</strong><br />

the proportionate area under fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables. It is important to note that change in<br />

crop pattern in terms <strong>of</strong> the proportion <strong>of</strong> area under crops represent the mechanism <strong>of</strong><br />

adjustment to adapt to or to take advantage <strong>of</strong> opportunities emerging out <strong>of</strong> changes in<br />

economic environment, accessibility to market, labour market, infrastructure <strong>and</strong><br />

technology. Changes in crop pattern could be an important source <strong>of</strong> output <strong>and</strong><br />

productivity growth even in the absence <strong>of</strong> technological advancement (Ch<strong>and</strong>, 1996)_<br />

Separate regressions is done for the periods, 1972-75 <strong>and</strong> 1998-2001<br />

"f"rp 1972-75 = 7927.84 + 549.17* PAFV<br />

-v~luc (3.761)<br />

R2~O.756, N=12<br />

107


TVP 1998-2001 = 1187.80 + 1089.33* PAFV<br />

t-value (3.\54)<br />

R2 = 0.706, N=12<br />

* Significant at I % level<br />

TVP: Total Value Productivity<br />

PAFV= Proportionate area under fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables<br />

The relationship between productivity levels <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> fruits<br />

<strong>and</strong> vegetable is high <strong>and</strong> significant. In other words, the change in productivity levels<br />

during early 1970s <strong>and</strong> late 1990s were significantly influenced by the diversification <strong>of</strong><br />

cropping pattern towards high value horticultural crops. The picture <strong>of</strong> different time<br />

period indicates that significance <strong>of</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> horticulturaJ crops has<br />

increased substantially.<br />

4.5. An Overview <strong>of</strong> Selected ViUages <strong>and</strong> Socio-Economic<br />

Characteristics <strong>of</strong> Farmers<br />

A multi-stage purposive sampling procedure was followed in order to select the<br />

state, district, block <strong>and</strong> villages. A district was chosen on the basis <strong>of</strong> how representative<br />

it is in diversification towards horticultural crops. On the basis <strong>of</strong> the temporal <strong>and</strong> spatial<br />

pattern <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>and</strong> horticultural development across blocks, Theog was chosen<br />

as the block <strong>of</strong> study. The sample was drawn from four villages, two villages each for<br />

fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables from this block as being representatives <strong>of</strong> diversification towards<br />

fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables respectively. Sample <strong>of</strong> 30 farm households was drawn from each <strong>of</strong><br />

the four villages with the aid <strong>of</strong> a stratified <strong>and</strong> proportional r<strong>and</strong>om sample approach '9 .<br />

Cauliflower <strong>and</strong> apple were chosen as the respective vegetable <strong>and</strong> fruits crop due to the<br />

higher diversification towards these crops in the selected villages.<br />

Table 4.8 provide the details <strong>of</strong> selected villages. In Village I <strong>and</strong> II, vegetables are<br />

grown extensively. These villages have respectively 592 <strong>and</strong> 398 hectare <strong>of</strong> total<br />

cultivated area out <strong>of</strong> which around 50% <strong>and</strong> 60% respectively is irrigated. Vegetables<br />

c'.v~r 72% <strong>and</strong> 84% respectively <strong>of</strong> the to~al gross area. Among vegetables, cauliflower, a<br />

19<br />

The details <strong>of</strong> sampling are provided in Chapter one<br />

108


water-intensive crop, is the favourite <strong>and</strong> covers most <strong>of</strong> the area in these villages,<br />

followed by bean <strong>and</strong> peas. Maize is one <strong>of</strong> the most prominent subsistence crops <strong>of</strong> the<br />

regions; all other food crops are produced at lower scale. The two villages (Village III<br />

<strong>and</strong> N), where fruits are grown at a higher scale, have 532 <strong>and</strong> 586 hectare <strong>of</strong> total<br />

cultivated area, <strong>of</strong> which respectively 30"10 <strong>and</strong> 12 % <strong>of</strong> area is irrigated. Apple is the<br />

major crop in these villages <strong>and</strong> covers 85% <strong>and</strong> 89% respectively <strong>of</strong> total cultivated<br />

area. Bearing apple trees cover only about 50"10 area in village III, pointing to the late<br />

onset <strong>of</strong> diversification. In village IV, the process <strong>of</strong> diversification commenced in the<br />

early part <strong>of</strong> 1900 when apple was introduced in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> by Mr. Stocks who<br />

came down from Holl<strong>and</strong>. In village III, considerable area is also under vegetables.<br />

Relatively higher level <strong>of</strong> irrigation in this village had made it possible to grow waterintensive<br />

vegetable crops, but, most <strong>of</strong> the area is now non-bearing apple trees <strong>and</strong> hence<br />

this region, like Village IV would reach a high level <strong>of</strong> specialisation in the near future.<br />

High amount <strong>of</strong> area being under bearing apple trees resulted in the low level <strong>of</strong> cropping<br />

intensity in these two villages.<br />

Table 4.8: Details <strong>of</strong> the Selected Villaaes<br />

-<br />

<strong>Crops</strong> Cauliflower<br />

VIII.ges<br />

Uait<br />

Number <strong>of</strong>fana Housebokl Numbers 146<br />

Total tultivated l<strong>and</strong> Net Cropped Area (Ha) 592<br />

T otallrrlg.ted l<strong>and</strong> Net Irrigated Area (Ha) 338<br />

Area Under crops<br />

Apple-Bearing Trees (Ha) 0<br />

Apple- Non-Bearing Tress (Ha) 0<br />

Other fruits (Ha) 15<br />

Vegetables (Ha) 945<br />

Food grains (Ha) 153<br />

Gross Cropped Area I (Ha) 1113<br />

Cropping Intensity I (Percentage) 188.01<br />

Note: I. Ha- Hectare<br />

ii. Village I,II,III,IV are Govai, Sainj, S<strong>and</strong>hu <strong>and</strong> Shilaru respectively<br />

Source: Primary Dala<br />

dOBlloated Apple dominated<br />

VOla ... Vill ....<br />

Village I vW"I_n ViDag.1II ViII·C_ IV<br />

174 148<br />

398 532<br />

198 192<br />

35 266<br />

52 186<br />

7 16<br />

508 118<br />

97 106<br />

699 692<br />

175.63 130.08<br />

The distribution <strong>of</strong> farm size differs in villages <strong>of</strong> both crop groups (table 4.9). In<br />

the base <strong>of</strong> fruits , these villages are dominated , by the semi-medium <strong>and</strong> medium farmers<br />

135<br />

586<br />

76<br />

410<br />

117<br />

29<br />

47<br />

99<br />

702<br />

119.80<br />

109


(own l<strong>and</strong> between 2-10 hectare), whereas, in the case <strong>of</strong>vegetables, small <strong>and</strong> marginal<br />

fanners (owns between 0-2 hectare) are in majority. Semi-Medium farmers are<br />

considerable in numbers in these villages, while medium <strong>and</strong> large farmers are small in<br />

numbers.<br />

Cauliflower<br />

Table 4.9: Farm<br />

-<br />

s· Izean dS amDllD1!. r f rom the Selected ViUal!.es<br />

<strong>Crops</strong><br />

Villages Village I Villagen<br />

Farm size<br />

Unit<br />

Marginal Farmon Less than I Ha 35 (7) 43 (8)<br />

Small Farmon 1·2 Ha 49(11) 67 (12)<br />

dom.inated Villages<br />

Semi-Medium Farmen 24Ha 37 (7) 48 (8)<br />

Medium Farmen 4-10 Ha 13 (2) 16 (2)<br />

Large F Brmen More than 10 Ha 14 (3) 0(0)<br />

*Note:<br />

i. Figures in parenthesis are the sample collected from each village<br />

Sou,ce: Primary Data<br />

Apple dominated ViDages<br />

Village III ViDageIV<br />

17 (3) II (2)<br />

47 (9) 29 (6)<br />

63 (14) 51 (12)<br />

IS (3) 30(7)<br />

6 (1) 14 (3)<br />

The demographic features <strong>of</strong> selected fanners show that there is not much<br />

difference in the age <strong>of</strong> the household head across villages <strong>and</strong> most <strong>of</strong> the households<br />

are headed by old persons (table 4.10). In many developing countries, it is the household<br />

head that generally takes the decision <strong>of</strong> resource allocations (Yilma, 2(05). It is<br />

expected that young farmers tend to take more risk <strong>and</strong> hence could make higher level <strong>of</strong><br />

l<strong>and</strong> allocation towards high value commercial <strong>and</strong> risky crops. The incidence <strong>of</strong><br />

illiteracy among the household head is quite high though fanners have many years <strong>of</strong><br />

experience in fanning <strong>of</strong> the selected crops. The households are mostly headed by male<br />

members <strong>and</strong> there is not much difference in the family size across villages. Interestingly,<br />

the dependency ratio is higher for the vegetable growers which mean that it could be a<br />

forced commercialization in absence <strong>of</strong> income from other sources. However, fruit<br />

growers are experiencing higher level <strong>of</strong> shortage <strong>of</strong> labour as indicated by higher l<strong>and</strong>labour<br />

ratio, which could act as a constraint in higher level <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation towards the<br />

selected labour-intensive crops.<br />

IIO


Table410 , : D em02rapJ h' Ie F eatures <strong>of</strong> tbe Selected Farmers<br />

Variables Indi.ators Cauliflower dominated Villages Apple domiDated Villl£es<br />

Age Mean age <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Village I Village II Total Villae" III Villae" IV<br />

60.43 58.63 59.53 61.13 61.50<br />

household head<br />

Education Number<br />

household<br />

<strong>of</strong> 13 13 13 9 13<br />

headed by<br />

illiterate<br />

Experience Average yerus <strong>of</strong> 17.30 11.36 14.33 20.40 23.46<br />

experience in<br />

farming (in<br />

numbe;)<br />

Gender Number <strong>of</strong> 3 9 6 7 7<br />

households<br />

headed by<br />

females<br />

Family SIze Average number 5.9 7.4 6.65 6.2 6.3<br />

<strong>of</strong> household<br />

members<br />

Dependency Average number 2.0<br />

ratio <strong>of</strong> household<br />

2.5 2.25 1.6 1.9<br />

member not<br />

involved in any<br />

earning activity<br />

RHource L<strong>and</strong>/Labour 2.37 3.90 3.13 4.35 7.56<br />

Constraint<br />

Source. Primary Data<br />

It is clear from the table 4.I I that farmers involved in fruit fanning are using higher<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> fertilizer per hectare than vegetable growers. Also, for vegetable growers, the<br />

intensity <strong>of</strong> irrigation is significantly high, which shows that irrigation plays vital role in<br />

vegetable fanning <strong>and</strong> that not all horticultural crops are suited to rain-fed regions, where<br />

irrigation facilities are not developed. Fruit crops are more labour-intensive in<br />

comparison to vegetable crops. Due to shortage <strong>of</strong> home labour, most <strong>of</strong> the apple<br />

growers are dependant on hired labour for crop production <strong>and</strong> marketing operations. It is<br />

also noticed that sizeable number <strong>of</strong> apple growers are also involved in non-farm income<br />

activities which provides additional money to the farmer for investment in crop<br />

production <strong>and</strong> marketing operations. Non-farm income also could hedge against farmrelated<br />

risk <strong>and</strong> may act as a factor in improving farmers' propensity towards allocating<br />

l<strong>and</strong> to high value commercial crops.<br />

Total<br />

61.31<br />

II<br />

21.93<br />

7<br />

6.25<br />

1.75<br />

5.95<br />

III


Table 4.11: Input Use Behaviour <strong>and</strong> Other Farm-related Characteristics <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Selected Farmers<br />

Variables Indieaton Cauliflower dominated Villa!!es Aj>ple dominated Villa!!es<br />

Fertilizer Use Fertilizer use kg<br />

pcrha<br />

Irrigation Share <strong>of</strong> net<br />

intensity irrigated area to<br />

net cropped area<br />

Labour hiring Percentage <strong>of</strong><br />

propeosities households<br />

hiring labour for<br />

fann purposes<br />

Non-Farm Percentage <strong>of</strong><br />

Income<br />

households<br />

earning non-farm<br />

income<br />

Assets VaIue Value <strong>of</strong> farm<br />

assets (in<br />

Rupees)<br />

Access to credit Percentage <strong>of</strong><br />

households<br />

obtaining credit<br />

from formal<br />

a£eDCV (Bank)<br />

Note.<br />

i. N=30 for each village<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

Villa2e I ViUa\lell Total ViUagem Village IV Total<br />

1.28 1.52 1.4 1.66 2.12 1.89<br />

57.04 49.86 53.45 11.47 10.29<br />

60.00 46.66 53.33 76.66 83.33<br />

20.00 73.33 46.66 46.66 66.66<br />

22740 36933 29836 35510 45150<br />

30.00 20.00 25 40.00 30.00<br />

10.88<br />

79.995<br />

56.66<br />

40330<br />

35<br />

4.6. Income <strong>and</strong> Risk from <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> Production<br />

There is a basic difference between the selected fruit <strong>and</strong> vegetable crops in terms<br />

<strong>of</strong> the gestation period involved in production <strong>and</strong> marketing options. Cauliflower is an<br />

annual crop, <strong>and</strong> the returns from the crop are related with corresponding year <strong>of</strong> cost.<br />

Apple is a perennial crop <strong>and</strong> there is a gestation period in production <strong>of</strong> 5-7 years after<br />

which farmers start getting production. The production cycle for apple also varies; after<br />

12-15 years <strong>of</strong> plantation only farmers start getting higher level <strong>of</strong> production from the<br />

crop. Additionally, apple is relatively less perishable as compared to cauliflower. More<br />

marketing opportunities exist for selling apple. These differences determine the returns<br />

<strong>and</strong> risk from either <strong>of</strong> the crops. Thus, the economics <strong>of</strong> the selected crops are worked<br />

out separately.<br />

112


4.6.1. Income <strong>and</strong> Risk from Cauliflower<br />

The aggregate cost <strong>and</strong> returns determine the viability <strong>of</strong> production <strong>of</strong> a crop.<br />

Difference in the farm size <strong>and</strong> its relation with costs <strong>and</strong> returns from the crop is <strong>of</strong> high<br />

importance. It is generally argued that due to the presence <strong>of</strong> scale economies, many<br />

small farmers prefer not to indulge in the production <strong>of</strong> high value crops (White <strong>and</strong><br />

Irwin, 1972, Pope <strong>and</strong> Prescott, 1980). Only farmers having larger holdings gain more<br />

economically from the high value crops, but it can be argued that larger resources are<br />

required as the farm size increases. Also, high managerial requirements <strong>and</strong> other<br />

resources might increases the transaction costs in producing the crop <strong>and</strong> make the high<br />

value crop production relatively less remunerative in large holdings. Additional factors<br />

like resource availability including irrigation <strong>and</strong> lahour, technology, capital<br />

intensiveness etc also may influence the overall returns from the crop. The decision <strong>of</strong><br />

allocation <strong>of</strong> different resources (l<strong>and</strong>, labour <strong>and</strong> capital) also affects the viability <strong>of</strong><br />

crop. In this context, costs <strong>and</strong> returns are computed <strong>and</strong> resource allocation examined<br />

across different farm size for cauliflower crop. In order to work out the cost <strong>and</strong> returns<br />

<strong>of</strong> cauliflower cultivation, cost <strong>and</strong> return concept propounded in Farm Management<br />

Studies in India are used.<br />

Resource allocation, especially use <strong>of</strong> fertilizer, chemical spray, <strong>and</strong> irrigation is<br />

important from the point <strong>of</strong> view <strong>of</strong> its impact on the viability <strong>and</strong> returns from the crop.<br />

Interestingly, the intensity <strong>of</strong> all vital resources including fertilizer, irrigation <strong>and</strong><br />

chemical spray declined with increase in farm size (table 4.12). In other words, there is a<br />

negative relation between the allocation <strong>of</strong> resources <strong>and</strong> farm size. This indicates that as<br />

the farm size increased, farmers probably faced more constraints <strong>of</strong> resources20. Decline<br />

in the use <strong>of</strong> intportant resources could affect the viability <strong>and</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong> the crop;<br />

this can be tested through the calculation <strong>of</strong> costs <strong>and</strong> returns. The following paragraph<br />

attempts an analysis <strong>of</strong> cost <strong>and</strong> returns <strong>of</strong> farm operations.<br />

" It'is found previously that as farm size incr",*", the availability <strong>of</strong> home labour decreases that increases<br />

dependency <strong>of</strong> farmers to increase costs<br />

113


Tbl412F<br />

tlCa on BY a I ower G rowers<br />

Farm Size Fertilizer Spray per Irrigation Share <strong>of</strong> Income from<br />

use per ba (in Rs) per ba (in Cauliflower to aggregate<br />

ba (in Rs)<br />

Rs) income <strong>of</strong> housebold*<br />

a e . : arm s· Ize an dReso uree All ti b C uro<br />

-<br />

Maf'ldnaI Farme .. 1816.41 2211.28 310.96<br />

Small Farme .. 1474.59 1679.73 220.74<br />

Medium Farme .. 876.35 1267.73 168.46<br />

Large Farme .. 729.94 901.30 109.16<br />

Note:<br />

i. Aggregate income includes both farm <strong>and</strong> non·farm income<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

56.57<br />

55.87<br />

50.90<br />

41.00<br />

The results demonstrate that as farm size increases both aggregate cost (C2) as well<br />

as paid-out cost <strong>of</strong> crop production declines (figure 4.4). This was expected as there was<br />

a decline in allocation <strong>of</strong> resources with the increase in farm size. Consequent, we noticed<br />

decline in the productivity, gross <strong>and</strong> net returns as the farm size increases. It is found<br />

that small farmers are able to obtain the highest productivity <strong>and</strong> returns from the<br />

production <strong>of</strong> cauliflower. In order to find the link <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation with farm size, all<br />

fann size are divided on the basis <strong>of</strong> proportion <strong>of</strong> area under cauliflower crop to the total<br />

net area. There are two categories; lower «.50) <strong>and</strong> higher (>.50) l<strong>and</strong> allocation to<br />

cauliflower (figure 4.5). The comparison <strong>of</strong> farmers with identical farm size illustrates<br />

that farmers with higher level <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation gains more by decline in cost per ha <strong>and</strong><br />

get increased net returns from the crop. This demonstrates that increase in l<strong>and</strong> allocation<br />

did prove remunerative <strong>and</strong> more pr<strong>of</strong>itable for the farmer, irrespective <strong>of</strong> the farm size.<br />

Higher extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation towards high value crop has a favourable effect on crop<br />

economy brought about hy a decline in per unit cost with increased returns from the crop.<br />

114


Figure 4.4: Economics <strong>of</strong> Cauliflower Crop<br />

150000 t--------------j<br />

I_ ".rpinal Farrnera<br />

I .Smell FarmefW<br />

,CSerTII·MedlUfTl Farmel"l<br />

1 C Medium <strong>and</strong> L.arge F~<br />

Cost per He Cost (Pliid out) YIeld Per Ha Gross rftims Net returns over Nat returns o-..r<br />

(C2) per He (KQ) p., Ha Cost 2 Pw He PIIi::t-oul cost<br />

"'Ho<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

Figure 4.6: Economics <strong>of</strong> Cauliflower by Farm Size for Different Level<br />

<strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Allocation<br />

150000<br />

f-<br />

~ 100000<br />

o<br />

t '.<br />

M_ ...., I<br />

I<br />

low (0- i High low(Q- High<br />

0.50) I (>0.51) 0.50) (>0.51)<br />

-<br />

~--<br />

l_(O- High '-(0- High<br />

050) (>0.51) 0.50) (>0,51)<br />

-., I S-Medi'n <strong>and</strong> IA ...<br />

.Coat per Ha (C2)<br />

i. PilICkIut Cost pel' Ha (Puchlsed)<br />

IOGrou rl'turl1ll Per HIlI<br />

10 Net returns over C2 ~ Ha<br />

8Net returna aver Pald-out 00II: Per ....<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

liS


Further, mean price, yield <strong>and</strong> income received by the cauliflower growers are<br />

calculated on the basis <strong>of</strong> three years data (table 4.13). The results demonstrate that<br />

medium <strong>and</strong> large fanners received relatively low price for their produce but faced less<br />

variability in the price. On the contrary, the same group <strong>of</strong> farmers experienced low yield<br />

along with high variability in crop productivity. Small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers' gets better<br />

price for their produce <strong>and</strong> their productivity <strong>of</strong> the crop is also higher.<br />

Tbl a e 413 T d" Pri<br />

"<br />

: ren ID cean d Y" Ie Id so fC au rfl lower c rop<br />

Farm Size Mean leyels <strong>of</strong> Mean levels <strong>of</strong> Yield<br />

Price <strong>and</strong> its <strong>and</strong> its variability<br />

variability<br />

Martrlnal Fannen 10.49 (1.62) 19447 (2835)<br />

Small Farmers 10.81 (1.58) 19359 (3005)<br />

Semi-Medium 10.78 (1.80) 17697 (2271)<br />

Farmers<br />

Medium <strong>and</strong> Large 8.44 (1.55) 13925 (3057)<br />

-.<br />

Farmers<br />

Note:<br />

i_ Data is calculated on the basis <strong>of</strong> fann level data <strong>of</strong> three years, 2004, 2005 <strong>and</strong> 2006<br />

ii. Price is in Rslkg, <strong>and</strong> Yield is in Production per hectare<br />

iii. Figures in the parenthesis are the St<strong>and</strong>ard Deviation.<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

Information on different prices <strong>and</strong> production realized by farmers in the last ten<br />

years was collected. Using different prices <strong>and</strong> production figures <strong>of</strong> cauliflower, the<br />

maximum, expected <strong>and</strong> minimum net income over the paid-out cost by the farmers are<br />

computed (figure 4.6). The result illustrated that the farmers who experienced high<br />

income in the event <strong>of</strong> favourable market <strong>and</strong> weather condition also lost the most when<br />

both price <strong>and</strong> production crashed. The picture <strong>of</strong> gain <strong>and</strong> loss is different, when one<br />

considers the same across different farm sizes (figure 4.7). Small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers<br />

lost the most when both the price <strong>and</strong> production crashed. But, medium <strong>and</strong> large farmers<br />

gained relatively more in the situation <strong>of</strong> favourable price <strong>and</strong> production conditions. It is<br />

the small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers who bear the brunt <strong>of</strong> price <strong>and</strong> production crashes. This<br />

demonstrates difference in the results, when one compares the three year average data<br />

with the expectation or experiences <strong>of</strong> the farmers over a period <strong>of</strong> time.<br />

116


Figure 4.8: Sensitivity Analysis <strong>of</strong> Income from Caulltlo_r<br />

o<br />

·'oaooo<br />

~<br />

I<br />

• ;\ ! I t<br />

~[) ,. \'~\}'f d f\<br />

., II ft I .', I '• •<br />

~\0U ~~ l~j~/~,:fi.·~~vy.:.~~,Jo<br />

...<br />

, 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 3 7 50<br />

F ....<br />

-+-- Mnimtm Incon'I/t ~<br />

C2<br />

----- Elq:)ecttd I~ 0-<br />

C2<br />

---.- Maximum Ir.::onB OWl<br />

C2<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

Figure 4.7: Sensitivity Analysis <strong>of</strong> Income from Caullftower by Fann<br />

Size<br />

,«OOOr--------------------------------------------<br />

.MBrga"*1 Fal'n'len<br />

.Small Firmer.<br />

D5eml-Medlum Fa",*"<br />

DMectum <strong>and</strong> large F~<br />

Expected<br />

income- peilbut<br />

'""'<br />

Ma;drT'lum<br />

neon.- C2<br />

Source: Primary Da13<br />

117


4.6.2. Labour Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Output Supply Estimates: A Pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

Function Approach<br />

Efficiency <strong>of</strong> agricultura1 production is an important aspect from the point <strong>of</strong> view<br />

<strong>of</strong> agricultural development in developing countries. Assessment <strong>of</strong> economic efficiency<br />

has implications for policy issues regarding price policy <strong>and</strong> input supply among others.<br />

Economic efficiency in this study is defmed in the context <strong>of</strong> a pr<strong>of</strong>it function as<br />

developed <strong>and</strong> applied by Lau <strong>and</strong> Yotopoulos (\972) in analyzing Indian agriculture.<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>it function shows pr<strong>of</strong>it as a function <strong>of</strong> prices only. Here, it is assumed that<br />

prices are determined exogenously. There is an advantage in estimating an indirect pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

function i.e., a function <strong>of</strong> prices <strong>and</strong> quantities <strong>of</strong> fixed factors <strong>of</strong> production as<br />

compared to estimating a production or revenue function that expresses quantity <strong>of</strong> output<br />

as a function <strong>of</strong> quantities <strong>of</strong> all inputs. The advantage is that no endogenous variable<br />

(output or input level) is included in the indirect pr<strong>of</strong>it function as an explanatory variable<br />

<strong>and</strong> therefore simultaneous equation problems or bias are avoided in the estimates. The<br />

reduced form elasticities obtained from an indirect pr<strong>of</strong>it function reflect the output<br />

supply response <strong>of</strong> a pr<strong>of</strong>it maximizing price-taking firm assuming constant prices <strong>of</strong><br />

variable factors. However, unlike the production functions elasticities, they do allow for<br />

the adjustment <strong>of</strong> the quantities <strong>of</strong> variable factors to an increase in the fixed factors. As<br />

the quantity <strong>of</strong> a fixed factor such as capital increases, the marginal productivity <strong>of</strong> all<br />

variable factors is expected to rise. This increase in the marginal productivity result in<br />

employing <strong>of</strong> more <strong>of</strong> variable factors. Under these conditions, the mutalis mut<strong>and</strong>is<br />

elasticities obtained from pr<strong>of</strong>it function is found to be more appropriate for policy<br />

analysis than the ceteris paribus elasticities obtained from a direct production function. It<br />

is known that the Unit Output Price (UOP) pr<strong>of</strong>it function is decreasing <strong>and</strong> convex in the<br />

normalized prices <strong>of</strong> variable inputs <strong>and</strong> increasing in quantities <strong>of</strong> fIXed inputs <strong>and</strong> in the<br />

prices <strong>of</strong> the output. The major property <strong>of</strong> the UOP pr<strong>of</strong>it function model is that it<br />

provides input (like labour) dem<strong>and</strong> as a function <strong>of</strong> normalized wage rate <strong>and</strong> quantities<br />

<strong>of</strong> ~ther inputs like l<strong>and</strong>, fertilizer, irrigation <strong>and</strong> capital.<br />

118


We have measured the output supply <strong>and</strong> factor dem<strong>and</strong> equations by using the<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>it function as provided by Lau <strong>and</strong> Yotopoulos (1972). Labour is treated as the only<br />

variable factor as only the wages paid to the labour vary across farmers. This is because<br />

prices <strong>of</strong> other factors <strong>of</strong> production i.e., fertilizer, chemicals <strong>and</strong> irrigation do not vary<br />

across fanners. Pr<strong>of</strong>it is calculated by using the price received by farmer in the current<br />

year <strong>and</strong> the price expected by them. The rationale for running two pr<strong>of</strong>it functions is that<br />

the price <strong>of</strong> vegetable crop fluctuates too <strong>of</strong>ten <strong>and</strong> price in any given year may be <strong>of</strong> less<br />

significance in the decision <strong>of</strong> farmers regarding the employment <strong>of</strong> the variable factors.<br />

The expected price also could influence the decision-making <strong>of</strong> the farmers. Currently,<br />

there is no study that tries to fmd the relative significance <strong>of</strong> one-year price <strong>and</strong> expected<br />

prices on the economic efficiency <strong>of</strong> the farmers. The model <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it function is given<br />

below.<br />

Consider a firm's production function as<br />

Y = i{XI ..... X.; Zl ..... z,.) --------------------1<br />

Where Y= Quantity <strong>of</strong> output; x= quantity <strong>of</strong> variable inputs <strong>and</strong> Z are quantity <strong>of</strong> fixed<br />

inputs<br />

The pr<strong>of</strong>it function from a single product is given as<br />

n = P. Y - Ifi Xi -----------------------------2<br />

where P <strong>and</strong> Y are the price <strong>and</strong> output respectively <strong>and</strong> ri is the unit price <strong>of</strong> the Xi<br />

variable input.<br />

Substituting 1 into 2 we get<br />

n=P. f(xl .... .x.; Zl ..... z,.) - Irj Xj ---------3<br />

Where 11 is pr<strong>of</strong>it defmed as current revenues less current variable costs, P= unit price <strong>of</strong><br />

outpu~, <strong>and</strong> fj = unit price <strong>of</strong> the ith variable input <strong>and</strong> Xj= quantity <strong>of</strong> ith input<br />

119


Dividing both sides <strong>of</strong> equation 3 by P, we get<br />

It' = P. f(Xl ••..• x,,; Zl •••.. z..) - Lr;' X; ----------4<br />

where It' is defmed as the unit output price (UOP) <strong>and</strong> r;' is the nonnalized price <strong>of</strong> the<br />

ith input<br />

The equation 4 may be solved for the optimal quantities <strong>of</strong> variable inputs X; s, as<br />

functions <strong>of</strong> the nonnalized prices <strong>of</strong> the variable inputs <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> the quantities <strong>of</strong> the fixed<br />

inputs. By converting the pr<strong>of</strong>it function (3) to the UOP pr<strong>of</strong>it function (4), we will have<br />

all functions used in the analysis in terms <strong>of</strong> relative prices.<br />

Labour is treated as the only variable factor <strong>of</strong> production <strong>and</strong> capital <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> as<br />

fixed factors. Using Shepard lemma, both the output supply <strong>and</strong> labour dem<strong>and</strong> functions<br />

are estimated below:<br />

Ln It' = Ln A + al Ln w + ~l Ln K + Il2 Ln T -----------------5<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

- w L Ill' = a I ---------------------------------------------6<br />

Where It' is UOP pr<strong>of</strong>it (total revenue less total variable cost, divided by the price <strong>of</strong><br />

output), w is the normalized wage rate, K is fixed capital, T is cultivable l<strong>and</strong> under the<br />

crop, L is the quantity <strong>of</strong> labour employed, <strong>and</strong> Ln is the natural logarithm.<br />

On the basis <strong>of</strong> the assumption that a farm maximizes pr<strong>of</strong>it subject to unknown<br />

exogenous disturbance, the additive error in the second equation may arise from the<br />

differential abilities to maximize pr<strong>of</strong>its or divergences between expected <strong>and</strong> realized<br />

prices. Given this specification <strong>of</strong> errors, it is apparent that Zellner's method, imposing<br />

known constraints on the coefficients in the equations, provides an asymptotically<br />

efficient method <strong>of</strong> estimation. Equations 5 <strong>and</strong> 6 were first estimated jointly imposing<br />

thi constraint that a 1 * is identical from both equations. Next, we proceeded to the<br />

additional hypothesis <strong>of</strong> constant returns 10 scale (~1 + p2= 1) in production by imposing<br />

120


the second restriction using Zellner Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SUR) method. The<br />

results <strong>of</strong> the jointly estimated equations, imposing the condition that «I is identical in<br />

both the equations by using the current year price <strong>and</strong> expected price are presented in<br />

tables 4.14 <strong>and</strong> 4.15 respectively.<br />

·able 414· . Joint Estimation <strong>of</strong> Pr<strong>of</strong>it Function <strong>and</strong> Labour Dem<strong>and</strong> Function with Current Price<br />

FllBction Parameter Single Zellner's method with restriction<br />

equation Unrestricted One Two restriction<br />

OLS restrietion al*= al* &<br />

(al*= al*) 111+ 112=1<br />

UOP Pr<strong>of</strong>it 110 ·9.385 ..(J.017 0.009 ..(J.910<br />

fundion aI-labour 0.190 0.188 -0.083 ..(J.083<br />

III-Capital 2.080 0.931 .133 1.010<br />

112-Area ·1.144 ·0.055 -0.121 ..(J.022<br />

Labour al ..(J.690 -0.084 -0.083 ..(J.083<br />

dem<strong>and</strong><br />

function<br />

Source: Pnmary Data<br />

Table 4.15: Joint Estimation <strong>of</strong> Pr<strong>of</strong>it Function <strong>and</strong> Labour Dem<strong>and</strong> Function with Expected<br />

Price<br />

FUDttion Parameter Single ZeHner'. method "ilb reslrittion<br />

equation Unrestricted One Two restriction<br />

OLS restriction gl*= ai'll &<br />

(al*=al*) 81+ 82=1<br />

UOPPr<strong>of</strong>it 80 -1.442 ..(J.027 ·0.010 ..(J.731<br />

function ai-labour -0.713 -0.785 ·0.156 -0.159<br />

III-Capital 2.880 1.130 0.172 0.790<br />

112-Area ·1.855 0.188 0.135 0.195<br />

Labour al -0.630 ·0.297 -0.156 -0.159<br />

dem<strong>and</strong><br />

function<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

It is clear from tables 4.14 <strong>and</strong> 4.15 that the UOP pr<strong>of</strong>it function is not only<br />

decreasing in wages but also convex. However, a difference is noted in terms <strong>of</strong> using<br />

current year price <strong>and</strong> expected price. The coefficient <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> is positive in the case <strong>of</strong><br />

expected price <strong>and</strong> not so when current year price is used. This might be so because<br />

prices <strong>of</strong> cauliflower fluctuate widely <strong>and</strong> due to the absence <strong>of</strong> any minimum price,<br />

fanner considers the most expected price in their decision-making. The coefficient <strong>of</strong><br />

capital is found high <strong>and</strong> positive in both the cases.<br />

Indirect estimates <strong>of</strong> production function coefficients can be obtained from the joint<br />

estimates <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it <strong>and</strong> labour dem<strong>and</strong> function. These estimates are consistent; a property<br />

121


that is absent in the estimates derived directly from production functions as estimated by<br />

ordinary least squares. The formula derived from Lau <strong>and</strong> Yotopoulos (1972) show the<br />

correspondences between the estimated coefficients <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it function <strong>and</strong> indirect<br />

estimates.<br />

Labour= all (ai-I)<br />

Capital= fll / (1- al)<br />

L<strong>and</strong>= 1321 (1- al)<br />

- -<br />

Table 4 16- Indirect Estimates <strong>of</strong> Production Function Coefficients<br />

Coefficient<br />

RestrictioDs<br />

None<br />

One<br />

Current price<br />

Labour -0.232 0.076<br />

L<strong>and</strong> -.0684 -0.112<br />

Cagital 1.\30 1.040<br />

Sum <strong>of</strong> elasticities 0.829 1.004<br />

Expected price<br />

Labour 0.439 0.135<br />

L<strong>and</strong> .1050 0.117<br />

Capital 0.532 1.140<br />

Sum <strong>of</strong> elasticities 0.967 1.150<br />

Source: Computed usmg pnmary data<br />

Two<br />

0.079<br />

-0.021<br />

0.940<br />

1.000<br />

0.137<br />

0.168<br />

0.693<br />

1.000<br />

The elasticities estimates for fanns, on the basis <strong>of</strong> expected pnce, have the<br />

expected signs <strong>and</strong> have statistical significance (table 4.16). In terms <strong>of</strong> current year<br />

prices, l<strong>and</strong> turns out to be negative. Capital in both the cases has high elasticity.<br />

Labour dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> reduced form output elasticities can be calculated m the<br />

following manner.<br />

From 6<br />

-wU7t= al<br />

Taking logs on both side, one get<br />

\n~=ln(-al)+In7t -lnw .................................................... 7<br />

Substituting this into the 5 one get,<br />

122


InL=In(-aI)+InA+(al-I)Inw+JlI InK+Jl2InT .............. 8<br />

The labour dem<strong>and</strong> function here is the function <strong>of</strong> nonnalized wage rate, l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

capital. The labour dem<strong>and</strong> elasticities with respect to the wage rate, l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> capital are<br />

given byoInLlaInw<br />

=aInltlaInw - 1<br />

<strong>and</strong> for l<strong>and</strong> it is<br />

oInL I a tnT =aInlt laInT<br />

<strong>and</strong> similarly for capital it is<br />

oInL I a InK =alnlt loInK<br />

The labour dem<strong>and</strong> elasticity with respect to the price <strong>of</strong> output is given by<br />

olnL I a Inp =oInL I 0 Inw<br />

olnw/oInp<br />

Table 4.17: Labour Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Reduced Form Output Elastici ties<br />

I Current vear price E,pected price<br />

L.bour dem<strong>and</strong> elasticities<br />

WaKe rate ·1.083 -1.159<br />

L<strong>and</strong> ·0.022 0.195<br />

Capital 1.0lO 0.790<br />

Price <strong>of</strong> output 1.083 1.159<br />

Reduced form output elasticities<br />

WaKe rate -0.083 -0.159<br />

L<strong>and</strong> -0.022 0.195<br />

Capital 1.0lO 0.790<br />

Price <strong>of</strong> output 0.083 0.159<br />

Source. Primary Data<br />

The labour dem<strong>and</strong> elasticities with respect to wage rate, l<strong>and</strong>, capital <strong>and</strong> price <strong>of</strong><br />

output, respectively, are -1.083, -0.022, 1.010 <strong>and</strong> 1.083 for present year price, whereas it<br />

:s -\.159,0.195, 0.790 <strong>and</strong> 1.159 on the basis <strong>of</strong> expected price (table 4.17). The reduced<br />

fonn output elasticities with respect to wage rate, l<strong>and</strong>, capital <strong>and</strong> price <strong>of</strong> output,<br />

123


espectively, are -0.0835, -0.0223, 1.010 <strong>and</strong> 0.0835 for present year production, whereas<br />

it is -0.159, 0.195, 0.79 <strong>and</strong> 0.159 on the basis <strong>of</strong> expected price. The own price elasticity<br />

<strong>of</strong> labour is greater than one in absolute value indicating an elastic response <strong>of</strong> labour<br />

utilization to wage rate. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, labour dem<strong>and</strong> also responds positively to<br />

increase in the endowments in l<strong>and</strong>, capital <strong>and</strong> increase in the expected price <strong>of</strong> the<br />

output. The high coefficient <strong>of</strong> capital indicates its importance on the greater use <strong>of</strong><br />

labour with increase in capital intensiveness. The positive coefficient for l<strong>and</strong> is<br />

consistent with a priori notions when price expectation is used <strong>and</strong> not on the basis <strong>of</strong><br />

current year price. Furthermore, the output response elasticities show that output<br />

decreases with an increase in the normalized wage rate. The output supply responds<br />

positively to change in the price <strong>of</strong> the crop though the coefficient is not high. One may<br />

also note that with the expected year price, the response <strong>of</strong> output to price tends to<br />

improve.<br />

As there is difference in the nature <strong>of</strong> cauliflower <strong>and</strong> apple crop, there is a need to<br />

use different concepts for working out the economics <strong>of</strong> both the crops. The production<br />

pattern <strong>of</strong> a fruit crop is different from that <strong>of</strong> vegetable crop. In general, there is a<br />

gestation period <strong>of</strong> around 5-7 years after the plantation <strong>of</strong> the crop to start getting any<br />

production. Therefore, there is a need to have different criteria to measure the economic<br />

viability <strong>of</strong> the fruit crop. This is done in the subsequent section.<br />

4.6.3. Income <strong>and</strong> Risk from Apple<br />

Use <strong>of</strong> fertilizer <strong>and</strong> chemical spray are important activities for viability <strong>and</strong> returns<br />

from the crop. Though, it is important to note that the results cannot be easily generalized<br />

in the case <strong>of</strong> apple crop due to the disparity in the years <strong>of</strong> planting trees with each farm.<br />

Interestingly, the results show that, like cauliflower, the use <strong>of</strong> fertilizer <strong>and</strong> chemical<br />

spray is found decreasing with increase in the farm size <strong>of</strong> apple growers (table 4.18). In<br />

other words, there is a negative relation between resource allocation <strong>and</strong> farm size.<br />

124


T a bl e 418 . : F arm S' lZean dR esource AU ocation b I>y ApI Ie G rowers<br />

Farm Size Fertilizer use Spray per Share <strong>of</strong> Income from<br />

per ha (in Rs) ha (in Rs) apple to aggregate income<br />

<strong>of</strong> household*<br />

Small <strong>and</strong> Marginal<br />

•<br />

Farmers 3177.78 3788.89 87.39<br />

Medium Farmers 2340.06 3167.87 80.47<br />

Large Farmers 1535.55 2388.73 79.50<br />

Note:<br />

i. Aggregate income includes both farm <strong>and</strong> non·fann income<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

i<br />

I<br />

Four measures are used to estimate the economic viability <strong>of</strong> apple as given below:<br />

S.No Measure Description<br />

1 Net Present The NPV is the sum <strong>of</strong> discounted net cash·flows over a period. It is a<br />

Value (NPV) relatively objective method <strong>of</strong> determining the improvement in output<br />

resulting from production. In the case <strong>of</strong> annual cash-flows, <strong>and</strong><br />

assuming the current year is 'year 0', the formula for NPV is:<br />

NPV ~ CF(O) + CF(I) + CF(2) + ..... + CF(n)<br />

l+r (1+r)2 (I+r)n<br />

where CF(n) is the net cash-flow for NPV purposes in period n <strong>and</strong> r<br />

is the discount rate. Note that the initial cash-flow is not discounted as<br />

it is the initial period <strong>of</strong> the beginning <strong>of</strong> the crop plantation (in period<br />

0).<br />

2 Benefit-cost The BC ratio is given by: BC - Discounted Sum <strong>of</strong> present values <strong>of</strong><br />

ratio (Be ratio) benefits (cash inflows) divided by the Discounted Sum <strong>of</strong> present<br />

values <strong>of</strong> costs (cash outflows). A BC-ratio above one implies an NPV<br />

greater than zero. In the case <strong>of</strong> single cash outflow (occurring in the<br />

first period), the benefit-cost ratio is also called the Pr<strong>of</strong>itability Index.<br />

The BC ratio is a useful measure because when there are a large<br />

number <strong>of</strong> crops, there may not be enough resources available to<br />

undertake them all, even if they all have high net present values. As a<br />

rule <strong>of</strong> thumb, picking the crop with the highest Be ratios can ensure<br />

maximum value for money in terms <strong>of</strong> contributin.o: to outcomes.<br />

3 Payback Period This method determines the point in time at which cumulative net<br />

cash-flows exceed zero. For a crop, large output at the beginning <strong>of</strong><br />

the project is followed by smaller net inflows for several periods, with<br />

the cumulative inflows eventually covering the initial outlay <strong>and</strong><br />

providing some net benefit. The point at which the initial outlay is<br />

covered is the payback period. The payback method has several major<br />

weaknesses. Firstly, it does not discount cash-flows (although<br />

discounting could be added). Secondly, it does not take account <strong>of</strong><br />

cash-flows beyond the payback period, which could be large <strong>and</strong><br />

affect the desirability <strong>of</strong> undertaking the project. Thirdly, it is a<br />

-<br />

measure <strong>of</strong> time, not a measure <strong>of</strong> value<br />

I 4 The Internal This method can be useful for crops for which it is very difficult to<br />

Rate <strong>of</strong> Return determine a suitable discount rate. The IRR is the discount rate which<br />

L (lRR) method would give an NPV <strong>of</strong> zero, .o:iven expected cash-flows.<br />

125


IRR-r,+ NDl_ (r,-r,)<br />

ND,+ND,<br />

Where r, is the last discount rate which makes NPV positive<br />

r 2 is the first discount rate which makes NPV negative<br />

NO, is the last positive NPV<br />

NO, is the flTSt negative absolute value <strong>of</strong> NPV<br />

For measuring the economics <strong>of</strong> apple crop, all the above mentioned measure are<br />

computed across farm size using the present year price which is Rs 25. The production<br />

cycle is worked out by using the last 30 years data <strong>of</strong> apple production in Shimla district.<br />

Hence, NPV has been calculated for the period <strong>of</strong> 30 years. Initially 10 % discount rate<br />

was used to measure the indicators <strong>and</strong> later the simulations have been done to find the<br />

impact <strong>of</strong> different discount rates, prices <strong>and</strong> costs on the economic viability <strong>of</strong> apple<br />

crop.<br />

The results are presented in table 4.19. Small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers have higher<br />

NPV as well as higher benefit-cost ratio <strong>of</strong> apple crop production as compared to the<br />

large farmers. However, large farmers generally have a lesser pay back period for getting<br />

returns from the apple cultivation. Large farmers also have lesser internal rate <strong>of</strong> return,<br />

which points to the better position <strong>of</strong> large farmers in comparison to smaller farmers in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> getting the total invested money back earlier. They face low discount rate, which<br />

is crucial in calculating the benefits from apple production.<br />

T able 4.19: Economics <strong>of</strong> Apple Production by Farm Size<br />

Farm Size NPV(in Benefit- Payback IRR(%)<br />

Rs.) Cost Ratio period (in<br />

(D/C) Years)<br />

Small <strong>and</strong> marginal<br />

Farmers 220892 1.54 14.17 14.44<br />

Medium Farmers 223873 1.55 14.12 14.71<br />

Larl!e Farmers 213901 1.49 13.65 13.84<br />

Source. Pnmary Data<br />

The simulation analysis is conducted in order to find the impact <strong>of</strong> difference in the<br />

expected price by the farmers, maximum price received by the farmers, as also by<br />

,acloring in an increase in cost by 1 Q% <strong>and</strong> increase in discount rate to 15%. The<br />

126


simulation analysis presents some interesting findings (table 420). The change in price<br />

from current year price to the price expected by the farmer tends to improve the position<br />

<strong>of</strong> small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers, who perform better in all four measures <strong>of</strong> cash flow<br />

analysis as compared to large farmers. In other words, small <strong>and</strong> marginal fanner have<br />

higher NPV <strong>and</strong> high benefit cost ratio along with lower pay back period <strong>and</strong> lower<br />

discount rate. But, in terms <strong>of</strong> the most favourable price received by the farmers, large<br />

farmers performed better in all counts. This is due to the advantage <strong>of</strong> large fanners in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> better bargaining power in the market to fetch higher prices. When there is an<br />

increase in discount rate from 10 to 15%, small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmer tend to perform<br />

better in terms <strong>of</strong> NPV <strong>and</strong> BIC but not in terms <strong>of</strong> IRR <strong>and</strong> payback period.<br />

changing the cost <strong>of</strong> production, no change in the relative position <strong>of</strong> farmers is observed<br />

in all the four measures. This shows that the impact <strong>of</strong> change in the tax <strong>and</strong> other<br />

policies may not have any affect on the redistribution <strong>of</strong> benefits <strong>and</strong> costs across<br />

different farm sizes.<br />

T a bl e 4 . 20 : S· Imu I· atioD An all'Sls I . 0 f A \pple I P r od UCtiOD b II}' F arm S· lze<br />

Simulations F ..... Size & Small <strong>and</strong> marginal Medium Fal'JDen Larp<br />

distribwtioa Farmers FarmUi<br />

NPV 130221.63 110142.89 124247.99<br />

ElJIOded pri .. @ Ble 1.08 1.02 1.06<br />

distonnt rate I O~. Payba


in India. It can promise higher output, productivity, employment <strong>and</strong> ensure sustainability<br />

<strong>of</strong> natural resources. Shift in .consumption pattern from staple to high value horticultural<br />

crops has been increasing the dem<strong>and</strong> for these crops. Higher allocation <strong>of</strong> area to these<br />

crops is bound to result in higher growth <strong>of</strong> the agricultural sector, as the relative prices<br />

<strong>of</strong> these crops are increasing fast. In <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>, higher allocation <strong>of</strong> area to<br />

horticultural crops has had beneficial results in terms <strong>of</strong> higher area productivity <strong>and</strong><br />

growth <strong>of</strong> value <strong>of</strong> output.<br />

The evaluation <strong>of</strong> economics <strong>of</strong> the selected horticultural crops shows that small <strong>and</strong><br />

marginal farms are more remunerative, especially because <strong>of</strong> application <strong>of</strong> more<br />

resources like fertilizer, use <strong>of</strong> chemical spray <strong>and</strong> irrigation. In addition, small <strong>and</strong><br />

marginal farmers get higher yield with less variabilitf. This probably helps them to<br />

exhibit higher level <strong>of</strong> allocation <strong>of</strong> area to horticultural crops. Higher level <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong><br />

allocation to the selected horticultural crop pays equally to small <strong>and</strong> large farmers as no<br />

such bias is found in the study. However, in a situation <strong>of</strong> unfavourable market <strong>and</strong><br />

weather conditions (crash <strong>of</strong> both price <strong>and</strong> production), small farmers suffer more. In the<br />

event <strong>of</strong> most favourable market <strong>and</strong> weather conditions (highest price <strong>and</strong> production),<br />

large farmers gains the most. This might be due to the advantage <strong>of</strong> large farmers in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> better bargaining power in the market compared to small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmer.<br />

The price expectation also plays an important in the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers.<br />

<strong>Horticultural</strong> crops are high value crops <strong>and</strong> in the study area, the selected<br />

horticultural crops are found to compete with food crops for l<strong>and</strong>. Though, small <strong>and</strong><br />

marginal farmers are able to obtain higher returns from these crops, scarcity <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

poor income base are likely to playa critical role in their decision-making regarding shift<br />

from food crops to commercial crops. They face the choice <strong>of</strong> trade-<strong>of</strong>f between their<br />

goal <strong>of</strong> food security <strong>and</strong> income maximization. At the same time, medium <strong>and</strong> large<br />

fanners have to face the constrains <strong>of</strong> resources including labour which may influence<br />

their decision regarding increasing allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> to horticultural crops that are highly<br />

labour <strong>and</strong> capital intensive crops. This calls for examining the role <strong>of</strong> economic <strong>and</strong> non­<br />

(cohomic factors in fanners' decision <strong>of</strong> diversifying their l<strong>and</strong> from low value food<br />

crops to high value horticultural crops.<br />

128


CHAPTER V<br />

ROLE OF ECONOMIC AND NON-ECONOMIC<br />

FACTORS IN DIVERSIFICATION FROM FOOD<br />

CROPS TO HORTICULTURAL CROPS<br />

5.1 Introduction<br />

Over a period <strong>of</strong> time, allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> changes across crops <strong>of</strong> different values.<br />

Due to changing l<strong>and</strong> allocations, cropping pattern shifts from low value to high value<br />

crops or vice versa. The issues relating to shifting l<strong>and</strong> allocation include typology,<br />

direction <strong>and</strong> magnitude <strong>of</strong> changing l<strong>and</strong> allocation across low <strong>and</strong> high value crops.<br />

The decision-making process relating to shifting area towards crops <strong>of</strong> different<br />

values is analysed at both macro (state or district) <strong>and</strong> micro (farm) levels. At the macro<br />

level, such decisions are examined on the basis <strong>of</strong> area supply response models initially<br />

introduced by Nerlove in 1958 <strong>and</strong> later on modified by many. The emphasis was on<br />

rmding the role <strong>of</strong> farmer's expectation <strong>of</strong> future prices in shaping their decisions in<br />

regard to the extent<strong>of</strong>l<strong>and</strong> they devote to crops. Nerlove (1958) devised a model relating<br />

expected "normal" price to past-observed prices. Many studies came later that used<br />

Nerlovian model with some modifications to investigate the importance <strong>of</strong> price <strong>of</strong> crop<br />

in shaping farmers' supply response behaviou1' (Krishna, 1963, Behrman, 1968, De,<br />

2005, Askari <strong>and</strong> Cummings, 1976, Sawant, 1978, Mythili, 2(06). However, there are<br />

several limitations that exist in analysing changing l<strong>and</strong> allocation decision, using macro<br />

level data.<br />

Measurement <strong>of</strong> supply response usually requires time series data for quantities, cost<br />

<strong>and</strong> prices. Such data are seldom reliable, available for short duration <strong>and</strong> provide partial<br />

coverage in terms <strong>of</strong> crops <strong>and</strong> area. As a result, a large number <strong>of</strong> crops especially high<br />

value horticultural crops are excluded from the analysis due to lack <strong>of</strong> reliable time series<br />

; Lpp\y response behaviour is 'he changing l<strong>and</strong> allocation among different crops due to change in<br />

economic values <strong>of</strong> crops_ The same is a proxy for diversification from food to horticultural crops in this<br />

chapter<br />

129


data. In addition, the time series data under conditions <strong>of</strong> tecbnological change <strong>and</strong><br />

variable weather constitute a weak basis for estimating supply response <strong>and</strong> hence fann<br />

level studies are more important in analysing such decisions (Medellin, et aI., 1994).<br />

Another limitation <strong>of</strong> these models is regarding identification <strong>of</strong> the competing crop.<br />

At any given time, not only two crops compete with each other for l<strong>and</strong> but there are<br />

possibilities <strong>of</strong> many crops competing for l<strong>and</strong>. In addition, the crops that compete for<br />

l<strong>and</strong> at a particular point <strong>of</strong> time vary across regions <strong>and</strong> farmers, due to heterogeneity in<br />

agro-climatic factors, among others. A macro picture cannot capture the difference in the<br />

choice <strong>of</strong> competing crops. Additionally, it assumes that only one crop competes with<br />

another crop. The supply response also varies across the groups <strong>of</strong> fanners who shift<br />

from food crops to commercial crops vis a vis the farmers who shift from one commercial<br />

crop to another. Price can be a vital component for the second group <strong>of</strong> farmers, whereas<br />

for the fIrst group, the concern for food security can be an important factor while making<br />

l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions. Hence, response elasticity <strong>of</strong> area to change in price is expected<br />

to differ for both groups <strong>of</strong> farmers.<br />

The macro level studies mainly concentrate on price <strong>of</strong> the crop as a major economic<br />

factor in shaping farmers' changing l<strong>and</strong> allocation decision. District or state consists <strong>of</strong><br />

disaggregated units, i.e. farmers <strong>and</strong> at farm level, there exists disparity in endowments<br />

<strong>and</strong> access to markets. Price alone may not be the factor in decision-making due to<br />

heterogeneity in the resource <strong>and</strong> capital endowments <strong>of</strong> farmers <strong>and</strong> difference in their<br />

access to input <strong>and</strong> output market. Varied influences are visible on prices <strong>and</strong><br />

productivity <strong>of</strong> the crop attained at farm level. It could be hypothesized that farmers with<br />

relatively higher level <strong>of</strong> productivity will allocate more l<strong>and</strong> to the crop even at lower<br />

expected price. Hence, it is important to examine the link between the price <strong>and</strong> income<br />

in the context <strong>of</strong> shifting cropping pattern decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers. Although, Deshp<strong>and</strong>e <strong>and</strong><br />

Ch<strong>and</strong>rasekhar (1980) attempted to study the role <strong>of</strong> net income in the farmers' decisions<br />

at the district level, heterogeneity in cost that varies across farms makes it more robust to<br />

Hudy such decisions at the micro level.<br />

I<br />

130


At the micro level, most studies contain analyses that are based on probability <strong>and</strong><br />

possibility like pay-<strong>of</strong>f, expected utility, betting, subjective probability distribution <strong>of</strong><br />

economic returns (price, yield <strong>and</strong> income) <strong>and</strong> possibility <strong>of</strong> returns (Arrow 1951,<br />

Shackle, 1949, Binswanger, 1981). The analyses based on the probabilities are criticized<br />

on the ground that farmers are seldom aware <strong>of</strong> the probability <strong>of</strong> economic outcomes but<br />

they know the possibility <strong>of</strong> different outcomes related to price, yield <strong>and</strong> income<br />

(Shackle, 1949) where possibility is a credible event. Shackle (1949) introduced the<br />

concept <strong>of</strong> expectations, focused 'gain <strong>and</strong> loss' in dealing with decision-making <strong>of</strong> the<br />

fanners 22 • But, there is hardly any empirical analysis based on his proposition. In other<br />

words, there are very few studies that have attempted to link the area reallocation<br />

decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers with their price <strong>and</strong> income possibilities or expectations. As the<br />

process <strong>of</strong> shift in cropping pattern can take place in two different directions, i.e., from<br />

low value to high value crops <strong>and</strong> vice versa, it is also important to examine the factors<br />

related to diversity in the· supply response to change in price <strong>of</strong> crops2J.<br />

In this context, micro-level decision making pertaining to area shift towards selected<br />

horticultural crops becomes important. Initially, it will be necessary to underst<strong>and</strong> price<br />

<strong>and</strong> area cycles <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops. It is also vital to identify the role <strong>of</strong> economic <strong>and</strong><br />

non-economic factors, including food security concerns in diversification decision as<br />

fanners reallocate their cropping pattern from food crops to commercial crops.<br />

Variability in area responsiveness <strong>of</strong> farmers growing cauliflower to change in its price is<br />

another aspect in analyzing their response to economic stimuli. The method involves<br />

observing the change in price <strong>and</strong> area allocation behaviour <strong>of</strong> sample farmers <strong>and</strong><br />

grouping them on the basis <strong>of</strong> supply response behaviour. Then, the factors which explain<br />

difference in response <strong>of</strong> area under cauliflower to change in its prices are identified. We<br />

then examined the relative role <strong>of</strong> price <strong>and</strong> income in the decision-making <strong>of</strong> farmers<br />

regarding reallocation from low value food crops to high value horticultural crops.<br />

2~ I. a decision is a process <strong>of</strong> commitment by the decision maker with an action scheme. whose outcome is<br />

unk?own. the question that should be raised is about the process in which such a decision is made.<br />

t.cc~rding to Shackle, the decision maker is concerned with the consequence <strong>of</strong> his choice in the future. As<br />

the outcome is not known before h<strong>and</strong>, he has to res·)rt to imagining the figure (expectation) <strong>of</strong> what will be<br />

~he possible outcome. This guides choices <strong>of</strong> decision maker (Crocco, 1976)<br />

.3 This can be done only in the case <strong>of</strong> annual crop like cauliflower <strong>and</strong> not for perennial crop like apple.<br />

131


Response to economic stimuli is, however one aspect <strong>of</strong> the impact <strong>of</strong> market forces on<br />

the cropping pattern change. Equally important are market infrastructure <strong>and</strong> institutional<br />

arrangements. The delivery system <strong>of</strong> inputs <strong>and</strong> credit are other important factors in<br />

determining cropping pattern decisions <strong>of</strong> the farmers (De, 2005). Thus, other noneconomic<br />

factors are also examined in analyzing farmers' decision regarding shifting<br />

from food to horticultural crops.<br />

5.2. Behaviour <strong>of</strong> Price <strong>and</strong> Area Cycles <strong>of</strong> Fruit <strong>and</strong> Vegetable<br />

<strong>Crops</strong><br />

Fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables are two distinct categories in horticultural crops in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

difference in their cyclic periods <strong>of</strong> production. The cycles tend to be longer for fruits<br />

because <strong>of</strong> the longer gestation period involved. Figure 5.1 depicts typical cyclical<br />

behaviour that could exist, i.e., divergent, convergent <strong>and</strong> continuous fluctuations. The<br />

first situation deals with divergent fluctuation, where the elasticity <strong>of</strong> supply is greater<br />

than the elasticity <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>. In this case, starting with a moderately large supply <strong>of</strong><br />

commodity in period 1 (Ql) <strong>and</strong> a corresponding price PI, the series <strong>of</strong> reactions is traced<br />

by the line drawn. In the second period, there is a moderately reduced supply (Q2) with a<br />

corresponding higher price P3. This high price calls for a considerable increase in supply,<br />

Q3 in the third period, with the consequent result <strong>of</strong> decline in price to P3, which further<br />

leads to decline in the quantity to Q4 in the next period. Under these conditions, the<br />

situation continue to grow more <strong>and</strong> more unstable, price falls to absolute zero or a limit<br />

is reached so that production could no longer exp<strong>and</strong>. The reverse situation, with supply<br />

less elastic than dem<strong>and</strong> in the next part <strong>of</strong> the diagram is the instance <strong>of</strong> convergent<br />

fluctuation. Here, starting with the large supply <strong>and</strong> low price in the first period, PI there<br />

would be a very short supply <strong>and</strong> high price, Q2 <strong>and</strong> P2 in the second period. Production<br />

would exp<strong>and</strong> again in the third period to Q3 but to a smaller production than that in the<br />

first period. This would set the low price, P3 in the third period with a moderate reduction<br />

in quantity to Q4 in the fourth period <strong>and</strong> a moderately high price P4. Overtime, the<br />

pr


Figure 5.1: Types <strong>of</strong> Area <strong>and</strong> Price Cycles<br />

Price<br />

P2<br />

Q3<br />

P2<br />

Q3<br />

Q2 P3 PI<br />

Q2<br />

QI<br />

Quantity<br />

QI<br />

Divereent Cobweb<br />

Convergent Cobweb<br />

Quantity<br />

Price<br />

Q3<br />

PI.P3<br />

QI<br />

Continuous Cobweb<br />

In the case <strong>of</strong> continuous fluctuation or cobweb, the quantity in the initial period<br />

Illo/ge, attracting a relatively low price where it intersects the dem<strong>and</strong> curve at P I. This<br />

low price, intersecting the supply curve, calls forth in the next period a relatively short<br />

133


supply Q2. This short supply gives a high price P2 where it intersects the supply curve.<br />

This high price calls forth a corresponding increased production, Q3 in the third period<br />

with a corresponding low price P3. Since, this low price in the third period is identical<br />

with that in the first, the production <strong>and</strong> price in the fourth, fifth <strong>and</strong> subsequent periods<br />

will continue to rotate around the path Q2, P2, Q3, P3 etc. As long as price is completely<br />

determined by the current supply, <strong>and</strong> supply is completely determined by the preceding<br />

price, fluctuation in price <strong>and</strong> production will continue in this unchanging pattern<br />

indefinitely without an equilibrium being reached. This is true in this particular situation<br />

because the dem<strong>and</strong> curve is exactly reverse <strong>of</strong> supply curve so that at their overlap each<br />

has the same elasticity (Ezekiel, 1938).<br />

The cycles for vegetable crops like cauliflower are expected to be smaller. A<br />

grower in a given season may receive high price relative to other years for the produce.<br />

Therefore, in the following season, farmer is expected to increase area under cauliflower<br />

as a response to high price. Other cauliflower growers receiving similar stimulus may<br />

also increase their area. If the season is good for the crop <strong>and</strong> the yields are high, the<br />

aggregate production <strong>of</strong> all growers will be in excess <strong>of</strong> the previous year <strong>and</strong> as a result<br />

prices will fall. Growers thus will be dissatisfied with the price <strong>and</strong> transfer some area to<br />

other crops, reducing the total crop marketed next year. The price may improve <strong>and</strong> the<br />

cycle starts again. This is primarily because there is generally no price support for this<br />

group <strong>of</strong> crops. This effect is particularly common in all vegetable crops where cycles are<br />

expected to be short.<br />

In order to analyze the pattern <strong>of</strong> area <strong>and</strong> price fluctuations, the data on the trend<br />

in area, production <strong>and</strong> productivity <strong>of</strong> cauliflower is collected for the last ten years from<br />

the Directorate <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>. Last three years' (2004, 2005, <strong>and</strong><br />

2006) data on prices <strong>of</strong> cauliflower could be obtained from the main market (Shimla)24.<br />

The seasonal prices <strong>of</strong> cauliflower are collected <strong>and</strong> grouped into three categories, i.e.,<br />

seasonal high, average <strong>and</strong> low. The trend in area under cauliflower shows increase over<br />

, i<br />

-. There is no fonnal agency that collects data on prices <strong>of</strong> vegetable crops_ Only the market committee in<br />

the district (capital <strong>of</strong> the state) collects data on prices <strong>and</strong> keeps these records on the monthly basis_ They<br />

provided only three years price data <strong>of</strong> Cauliflower crop.<br />

134


a period <strong>of</strong> time (table 5.1). However, it stagnated in the last year only. interestingly, the<br />

preceding year experienced the lowest price (table 5.2), but the total area under this crop<br />

did not decline, though remained stagnated. This may be because many farmers also<br />

responded perversely to prices due to their expectation <strong>of</strong> increase in the price ahead in<br />

the yeal'. The trend in production <strong>and</strong> yield has always been fluctuating without trend<br />

towards any specific direction.<br />

Tbl a e SIAr . : rea. P ro d uction an dY' Ie I d 0 fC ault 'n ower in Shimla. HP, 1998-2006<br />

Years Area (ha) Production (Tonnes) Yield (ToDBeslha)<br />

1998-99 325 6535 20.11<br />

1999-00 345 6755 19.58<br />

2000-01 355 6600 18.59<br />

2001-02 340 6560 19.29<br />

2002-03 360 7015 19.49<br />

2003-04 365 8325 22.81<br />

2004-05 400 8854 22.14<br />

2005-06 420 9240 22.00<br />

20()6.07 420 9106 21.68<br />

Source: Directorate <strong>of</strong> Agnculture, Shiml., lIP<br />

-<br />

Table S 2' Seasonal Price <strong>of</strong> Cauliflower in Shimla HP 200406<br />

, ,<br />

~. ' .<br />

Years<br />

Seasonal high<br />

Seasonal Low<br />

Seasonal Average<br />

2004-05 240<br />

2005-06 115<br />

20()6.07 435<br />

Note:<br />

i. Cauliflower Prices are in Rs per 20 kg<br />

Source: Shimla Market, Dhalli, Shimla<br />

180 150<br />

25 50<br />

110 225<br />

For apple, data for last ten years is obtained from the Directorate <strong>of</strong> Horticulture on<br />

its area under bearing trees <strong>and</strong> non-bearing trees, production, <strong>and</strong> productivity (table<br />

5.3). The data on wholesale price <strong>of</strong> apple is obtained from the National <strong>Horticultural</strong><br />

Board (NHB). Four months average <strong>of</strong> the prices is taken (August-November), which<br />

coincide with the harvesting season as farmer gets prices for their produce only during<br />

these months <strong>and</strong> they do not have access to storage facility. Companies like Reliance<br />

" This behaviour was noticed in case <strong>of</strong> majority <strong>of</strong> the farmers interviewed<br />

135


<strong>and</strong> Adani procure <strong>and</strong> store apple <strong>and</strong> sell it in different part <strong>of</strong> the countIy at different<br />

times 26 •<br />

Adjustments are expected to be completely discontinuous in the case <strong>of</strong> apple. A<br />

large swing in area change under non-bearing apple trees is indicative <strong>of</strong> the response <strong>of</strong><br />

farmers by adjusting planned area in the light <strong>of</strong> their expectation <strong>of</strong> prices. However,<br />

there is some gestation period <strong>and</strong> plantation varies over years, <strong>and</strong> nothing concrete can<br />

be said about their production response to prices. Farmers generally could respond to any<br />

single year price by deciding whether to plant more trees next year or not. In the data,<br />

there is no clue <strong>of</strong> any immediate response from farmers that links any single year price<br />

to next years' decision on the area to be brought under non-bearing apple trees as peaks<br />

<strong>and</strong> troughs in prices does not follow peaks <strong>and</strong> trough in area under non-bearing apple<br />

trees (figure 5.2). In many developing countries, the markets are generally small which<br />

either do not have the capacity to store or capacity to ensure some minimum price to the<br />

producers (Singh et ai, 2004). Thus, farmer may not influence the market prices through<br />

storage. The only option available to them is either to sell through different markets or<br />

sell for processing. The support price for apple is quite low Rs. 4.25 per Kg. Farmers give<br />

only low grade apples for processing which may not fetch good price in the market. In<br />

such a situation, they save on the expenditures on boxes <strong>and</strong> avoid transport cost as they<br />

sell the produce in the local market.<br />

U Reliance <strong>and</strong> Adani group initiated their operations in the Shimla district in 2006.<br />

136


5.3. <strong>Diversification</strong> from Food <strong>Crops</strong> towards <strong>Horticultural</strong><br />

<strong>Crops</strong><br />

Shift in cropping pattern towards the selected horticultural crops is measured on the<br />

basis <strong>of</strong> reference to the major changes made in terms <strong>of</strong> reallocating l<strong>and</strong> from food crop<br />

to chosen horticultural crop in the past seven years27. The economic variables which link<br />

successive time periods are the attitudes <strong>and</strong> the expectations <strong>of</strong> farmers <strong>and</strong> the<br />

entrepreneurial decisions or acts which are motivated by thern. These attitudes, decisions<br />

<strong>and</strong> acts influence the position attained by the farm in later period <strong>of</strong> time (Williams,<br />

1951). Thus, in order to assess decision making process <strong>of</strong> farmers, the time <strong>of</strong> major<br />

change in cropping pattern made by them is used as a proxy for shift in area which also<br />

has influence on the prevailing pattern <strong>of</strong> crop mix or l<strong>and</strong> allocation to crops.<br />

The questionnaire is designed to include various aspects relating to area reallocation<br />

by farmers. Initially, a seven year view (1999 - 2006)28 was taken <strong>and</strong> questions were<br />

asked like,<br />

1. When the farmer has made any change in the cropping pattern from food crop to<br />

the selected horticultural crop;<br />

2. When did they experience the major change towards horticultural crop;<br />

3. How much area was reallocated from a food crop to horticultural crop;<br />

4. Whether the addition <strong>of</strong> area to horticultural crop was done by substitution <strong>of</strong> a<br />

food or other commercial crop or is it done by extensification <strong>of</strong> area under<br />

cultivation;<br />

27 We exercised caution regarding the decision <strong>of</strong> fe-plantation <strong>and</strong> new plantation <strong>of</strong> apple crop while<br />

conducting the interview, as it otherwise would not have let capture the process <strong>of</strong> diversification by the<br />

fanners. Last three years data on fanner's area allocation among crops is also taken, the same is not used<br />

for proxy for shift in cropping pattern towards horticultural crops. This is especially so as majority <strong>of</strong> the<br />

cauliflower growers have not changed any area under the crop. In addition, in case <strong>of</strong> fruits, farmers 9<br />

iecision <strong>of</strong> allocating area is generally inflexible <strong>and</strong> unidirectional in ~he short run <strong>and</strong> it is not based ~n<br />

th~ response to year to year price. Few years' data on area <strong>and</strong> pnce may not capture the area shl'fi<br />

de~isions <strong>of</strong> the farmers growing fruits especially apple. .<br />

" This period was selected on the basis <strong>of</strong> the discussion with Revenue Officer (Patwan) <strong>and</strong> head <strong>of</strong> the<br />

village in terms <strong>of</strong> diversification pattern in the selected villages<br />

138


5. What were the previous years' price <strong>and</strong> yield, <strong>and</strong> what were price <strong>and</strong> yield<br />

thresholdsllevels ~t influenced their decision to reallocate area in favour <strong>of</strong><br />

horticultural crops?<br />

In the case <strong>of</strong> sampled fanners, it is noticed that shift <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern towards<br />

apple was made from two crops i.e., wheat <strong>and</strong> maize, whereas, cauliflower growers had<br />

shifted only from one crop i.e., wheat. The major change in the cropping pattern in favour<br />

<strong>of</strong> the selected horticultural crop happened in the year 2002 <strong>and</strong> 2003 <strong>and</strong> majority <strong>of</strong> the<br />

farmers shifted from food crops to the horticultural crops only once in the past seven<br />

years 29 • Such shifts were by substitution <strong>of</strong> food crop with few exceptions 3o • Both the<br />

absolute <strong>and</strong> relative measure for shifting area in favour <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops are<br />

measured; these inc1ude- amount <strong>of</strong> area changed from food crop to selected horticultural<br />

crop; area changed from food crop to selected horticultural crop with respect to the initial<br />

area under selected horticultural crop <strong>and</strong> with respect to net cultivated area <strong>of</strong> the fann.<br />

The typology <strong>of</strong> reallocation <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern indicates that shift with respect to<br />

initial area is high by the fanners growing cauliflower, whereas shift with respect to net<br />

cultivated area is higher for apple growers (table 5.4). More than 100% change with<br />

respect to initial area in total signifies the importance <strong>of</strong> diversification towards high<br />

value crops in these villages. Cauliflower is <strong>of</strong> more significance in Govai (village I) in<br />

comparison to Sainj (village II) even though Sainj has higher intensity <strong>of</strong> irrigation. This<br />

reflects the role <strong>of</strong> other economic, non-economic <strong>and</strong> financial factors that influence<br />

area under the crop. In the case <strong>of</strong> apple, the crop contributed more to the aggregate value<br />

<strong>of</strong> output obtained from the farm in Shilaru (village IV) as compared to S<strong>and</strong>hu (village<br />

1lI). This is primarily due to more area under bearing apple trees than non-bearing apple<br />

trees in village IV, as the crop was adopted much earlier in this village. However, shift <strong>of</strong><br />

29 Although, in case <strong>of</strong> cauliflower crop. some farmers have reversed the decision <strong>of</strong> shifting area to food<br />

crop, the same data is not used as a proxy for diversification towards horticultural crops. This data is<br />

utilized in the fourth section <strong>of</strong> this chapter in order to examine diversity in response <strong>of</strong> farmers to change<br />

In crop prices.<br />

JOlIn case <strong>of</strong> cauliflower, only one fanner has extended the area, whereas for apple crop, there are f?",<br />

fanners who have extended the area for increasing the importance <strong>of</strong> the gIven crop 10 theor cropplOg<br />

pattern mix.<br />

139


area towards apple in both villages is leading to higher level <strong>of</strong> specialisation as indicated<br />

by the number <strong>of</strong> crop produced in a year <strong>and</strong> the Herfmdahl index.<br />

Table 5.4: TypolO2Y <strong>and</strong> Extent <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> towards <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong><br />

Variable 1D1cator Cauliflower dominated Villages Apple dominated VUlages<br />

Villa2e I Vma.e" Total Village UI Vma.elV<br />

loitial Area (hal A 658 7.70 14.28 29.52 44.00<br />

Shift in area UDder !Au·~l<br />

diversified crop A,.<br />

w.r.t. InItial Area<br />

('!o) 108.93 179.39 144.16 65.54 62.57<br />

Shift in area uDder !Au. ~.l<br />

divenified crop NCA<br />

w.r.t.<br />

Net<br />

Cultivated Area<br />

('!o) 24.50 31.33 27.91 33.71 35.94<br />

Sbare <strong>of</strong> diversified (a,Il:A)<br />

crop area to total<br />

area after shift iB<br />

crooom2 .attern 49.95 54.21 46.47 70.05 67.18<br />

Share <strong>of</strong> diversified (v,ll:v)<br />

crop value to total<br />

value <strong>of</strong> output<br />

after shift ia<br />

croopm2 .attern 65.12 74.41 68.45 7\.63 8 \.66<br />

Diversity in<br />

Average<br />

Cropping Pattern Number <strong>of</strong><br />

crops<br />

produced in<br />

a vear 4.1 4.3 4.2 3.10 3.57<br />

Index <strong>of</strong> Herl"mdahl<br />

concentration Index 0.69 0.70 0.689 0.38 0.43<br />

Note:<br />

i. (A H<br />

• A.o F Difference in the area at the time <strong>of</strong> changing the area under the particular crop<br />

ii. (a;LAF proponion <strong>of</strong> area (a) under particular crop (i) in the total cropped area (A)<br />

iii. (V;fLV}= proponionate value (v) <strong>of</strong> a particular crop (i) in the total value <strong>of</strong> the farm output (V)<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

To",1<br />

73.52<br />

64.05<br />

34.82<br />

68.85<br />

73.08<br />

3.33<br />

0.41<br />

All<br />

VillA2es<br />

87.80<br />

104.10<br />

31.37<br />

5425<br />

70.39<br />

3.76<br />

0.557<br />

The results <strong>of</strong> distribution <strong>of</strong> shift towards selected horticultural crops across<br />

different farm sizes illustrate that in the case <strong>of</strong> cauliflower. large farmers have shifted<br />

the highest extent <strong>of</strong> area followed by the category <strong>of</strong> marginal farmers (table 5.5). This<br />

shows that marginal farmers have been able to diversify to a great extent while<br />

maintaining relatively higher level <strong>of</strong> subsistence. Not much difference in extent <strong>of</strong> shift<br />

is noticed across farm sizes for apple growers. Even after reallocation <strong>of</strong> area, cauliflower<br />

growers have a higher level <strong>of</strong> spread as against the apple growers who are getting highly<br />

specialized due to shift in cropping pattern. It is interesting to note that l<strong>and</strong>-labour ratio<br />

riles with the increase in the farm size for both the crops pointing to increased scarcity <strong>of</strong><br />

140


labour with increase in area under horticulturaJ crops. Big fanners are hence expected to<br />

be more dependant on the hired labour for higher allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> to horticultural crops.<br />

Ta bl e SST •• l'VP OI02V I 0 fD' Iversification towards <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> by Farm Size<br />

Arta under Area under Shift in area ProportioD <strong>of</strong> Levd<strong>of</strong> Number <strong>of</strong> L .. dlL ........<br />

diversified crop diversified crop IlDder divtrSifitd diversified crop Conteatratiou rops produce( Ratio··<br />

before mitt ill after crop"'.r .t.laitiaI .rea to total .rea ill. Year<br />

cropping p.ttent sbift ill ':O~":l<br />

....<br />

-<br />

(ba)<br />

(ii.i ..... m ba 1'1.'<br />

l.dicMor A" A.,-A" {AtI::~) (a,Il:A) HI'<br />

~A..<br />

Call1iflower domillated Villactl<br />

Marginal 2.50 3.44 137.50 58.33 0.71 3.10<br />

1.39<br />

Sman 6.69 725 108.41 52.67 0.73 4.04<br />

Semi-mcdiom 3.31 3.81 115.09 51.78 0.77 4.37<br />

Medium 1.38 1.63 118.18 35.20 0.65 5.00<br />

l.arge 1.50 6.25 416.67 62.61 0.78 5.00<br />

Apple do ..... ' ... Villages<br />

Marginal 2.00 2.88 65.71 71.62 0.43 2.00<br />

SmaD 2.32 8.25 55.93 72.98 0.37 2.54<br />

Semi-medium 3.76 22.00 74.26 69.06 0.49 3.30<br />

Medium 5.51 11.06 57.84 51.86 0.45 3.70<br />

Large 10.25 5.63 54.88 66.90 0.56 3.89<br />

• Herfindahllndex (Hl)<br />

•• L<strong>and</strong> is the net cultivated area <strong>and</strong> labour is number <strong>of</strong> agricultural labour at borne<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

5.3.1 Food Security Concerns in <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

2.00<br />

2.32<br />

3.76<br />

5.51<br />

2.08<br />

2.74<br />

4.32<br />

6.16<br />

6.32<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the major features <strong>of</strong> farming sector in the developing countries is the coexistence<br />

<strong>of</strong> subsistence <strong>and</strong> commercial crop production by large number <strong>of</strong> farmers<br />

(Narain, 1965)_ Concerns <strong>of</strong> food security for the family could hinder higher shift in<br />

cropping pattern (crop substitution) from food crop to commercial crop. However, for<br />

many <strong>of</strong> the commercial crops, especially horticultural crops, the earnings are high,<br />

which tend to improve the food security position <strong>of</strong> the family through higher net income<br />

from fanning. This might lead to increase in the consumption level <strong>and</strong> their st<strong>and</strong>ard <strong>of</strong><br />

living. However, high fluctuation in the prices <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops could potentially<br />

prove detrimental to the food security <strong>of</strong> the farm household. High variability in returns,<br />

higher cost <strong>of</strong> obtaining food from the market due to lack <strong>of</strong> infrastructure <strong>and</strong> overall<br />

lor income <strong>of</strong> fanners might force them to engage in more <strong>of</strong> subsistence crop<br />

production (Jayne, 1994; Nowshirvani, 1971).<br />

141


include:<br />

For the details on food security several questions were asked to the farmers, which<br />

I. Were they food self-sufficient or not at the time <strong>of</strong> shifting area from food crop<br />

to the selected horticultural crop?<br />

2. Whether at present their food grain consumption is influenced by the changes in<br />

prices <strong>of</strong> food grains in the market.<br />

The results indicate that majority <strong>of</strong> the farmers who had diversified towards<br />

cauliflower were food-self-sufficient before they undertook shift in cropping pattern,<br />

whereas this is not the case for farmers who diversified towards apple (table 5.6). This<br />

could be mainly because <strong>of</strong> relatively high returns from apple crop as compared to<br />

cauliflower. Also, the family size as. well as level <strong>of</strong> dependency ratio is larger for<br />

farmers growing cauliflower, which probably resulted in difference found in the extent <strong>of</strong><br />

shift in cropping pattern decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers 31 . However, both cauliflower <strong>and</strong> apple<br />

growers are less responsive to the change in the prices <strong>of</strong> food grains in tenns <strong>of</strong><br />

changing their consumption. Apple growing farmers are less responsive to price change<br />

due to gross margin from the crop which is so high that it is sufficient to cover more than<br />

four to five years <strong>of</strong> farm <strong>and</strong> non-farm expenditure <strong>of</strong> fann families, in general. For<br />

cauliflower, prices does go very low sometimes but according to farmers this trend does<br />

not last for more than one year due to which they are confident <strong>of</strong> getting good returns<br />

over a period <strong>of</strong> time. Easy access to credit allows them to hedge against the loss created<br />

either by production or price decline in any given year. Farmers mentioned another<br />

reason for this behaviour in the interview. They believe that there is abundance <strong>of</strong> food<br />

crops in the state <strong>and</strong> the prices <strong>of</strong> food crops are very low due to the higher level <strong>of</strong><br />

production <strong>of</strong> these crops in adjoining states (Punjab <strong>and</strong> Haryana). They have never<br />

faced any problem in obtaining food crops from the nearby market <strong>and</strong> that too at low<br />

price.<br />

)] Details <strong>of</strong> the socio-cconomic characteristics or the selected farmers is given in Chapter four<br />

142


TGable 5.6: Cropping Pattern Shift <strong>and</strong> Food Self-Sufficiency among <strong>Horticultural</strong> Crop<br />

rowers<br />

Cauliflower dominated Villages<br />

Apple dominated Villages<br />

Village I Village II Village Village IV<br />

III<br />

Whether farmer shifted from Yes 63.33 66.66 13.33<br />

being food .elf-sufficient (0,,) No 36.67 33.34 86.67<br />

Whether increase in prices <strong>of</strong> Yes 19.33 23.33 13.33<br />

food grains reduces its<br />

No<br />

Consumption (%)<br />

80.67 76.67 86.67<br />

Level <strong>of</strong> sUbsistence before<br />

Shift in CrOnnillf1. Pattern' (%)<br />

Level <strong>of</strong> subsistence after<br />

42.54 38.33 22.84<br />

Shift in CrOnnillf1. Pattern' (~o)<br />

Note:<br />

24.26 29.49 5.33<br />

~: F~gures in terms. <strong>of</strong> percmtage,. where for each village N is 30<br />

II. Level <strong>of</strong> SUbsIstence: Calculated as proportiooate <strong>of</strong> area under subsist ..... crops to total cropped area<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

30.00<br />

70.00<br />

16.67<br />

83.33<br />

35.47<br />

6.22<br />

The significance <strong>of</strong> farm size on the shift in cropping pattern through its impact on<br />

food crop production show that the marginal fanners have maintained relatively higher<br />

level <strong>of</strong> subsistence after shift in their cropping pattern from food crop to commercial<br />

crops (table 5.7). Extent <strong>of</strong> subsistence is very low for apple growers <strong>and</strong> the same has<br />

shrunk to a great extent after shift in cropping pattern. This is because introduction <strong>of</strong><br />

new varieties <strong>of</strong> vegetable crops enabled them to produce vegetable crops in the area<br />

which was under non-bearing apple trees. In the long run, they are unwilling to be called<br />

as vegetable farmers due to two reasons; lack <strong>of</strong> relatively better <strong>and</strong> stable gross margin<br />

in vegetables <strong>and</strong> higher social value associated with apple growers <strong>and</strong> not with the<br />

vegetable growers.<br />

T able 5.7: Level <strong>of</strong> Subsistence among the <strong>Horticultural</strong> Crop Growers bv Fa rm Size<br />

Cauliflower dominated<br />

ViIll2es<br />

Farm size Unit<br />

Marginal Less than I Ha 34.04<br />

Farmers<br />

SmaUFarmen \-2 Ha 22.92<br />

Semi-Medium 2-4Ha 23.18<br />

Farmers<br />

Medium Farmers 4-\0 Ha 23.68<br />

Large Farme" More than 10 Ha 26.04<br />

Note:<br />

i. The Fi gures arc in percentage, where N for each category is 60<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

Apple dominated<br />

VilIaRes<br />

13.48<br />

2.55<br />

5.31<br />

6.27<br />

7.37<br />

143


5.3.2. Relative Significance <strong>of</strong> Economic <strong>and</strong> Non-Economic<br />

Factors in <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

<strong>Horticultural</strong> crops are commercial crops with high productivity <strong>and</strong> income levels.<br />

In addition to this, these crops have several other advantages that are expected to sway<br />

the fanner while taking diversification decisions. Especially, horticultural crops are<br />

characterized as highly resource intensive crops which require huge amount <strong>of</strong> labour,<br />

investment etc. Not only the production but also the marketing <strong>of</strong> these crops dem<strong>and</strong><br />

huge investment; marketing expenditure constitute around one-third <strong>of</strong> the aggregate<br />

expenditure. In addition, since these crops are competing with food crops, it is vital for<br />

farmers to identify its relative importance. In order to underst<strong>and</strong> this, farmers were asked<br />

about their relative preferences to several economic <strong>and</strong> non-economic factors while<br />

taking decisions <strong>of</strong> shift from food crop to horticultural crops. Six key variables were<br />

selected <strong>and</strong> fanners were asked to rank these from one to six in descending order. Then,<br />

the weighted mean for all the six categories was calculated by using weights to ascertain<br />

the value <strong>of</strong> the relative importance <strong>of</strong> the variables in influencing farmers' decision to<br />

shift from food crops to horticultural crops. The formulae for weighted mean is<br />

6<br />

Weighted mean = L WjXj<br />

i=1 n<br />

Where Wi are the non-negative weights for all six categories (for instance, the<br />

variable ranked one is the most important <strong>and</strong> gets a weight <strong>of</strong> six; ranked two gets a<br />

weight <strong>of</strong> five; ........ ranked six gets a weight <strong>of</strong> one so that the most important factor<br />

will get the highest weight), Xi are the number <strong>of</strong> responses for the i lb category/variable<br />

<strong>and</strong> n is the total number <strong>of</strong> farmers who ranked the variables which is 60.<br />

The results show that for both the crops, price is the most important factor in the<br />

1versification decision <strong>of</strong>farmers (table 5.8). But, ~agnitude-wise, other fac~ors are al.so<br />

quite crucial. Labour availability <strong>and</strong> food producuon from l<strong>and</strong> are more cnllcal, while<br />

144


diversifying from food crop to apple; the significance shifts to inigation <strong>and</strong> productivity<br />

<strong>of</strong> the crop in the case <strong>of</strong> cauliflower, which is primarily because cauliflower is a waterintensive<br />

crop. Food availability is not a real problem for cauliflower growers especially<br />

because <strong>of</strong> the availability <strong>of</strong> one more season in a year for growing food crops. It is also<br />

due to the scope for flexibility in decision involved in cauliflower cultivation. In other<br />

words, while taking a diversification decision farmers are conscious <strong>of</strong> the flexibility in<br />

the decision in terms <strong>of</strong> shifting from one crop to another at any point <strong>of</strong> time. Such<br />

flexibility is absent when farmers plan to diversify from a food crop to a fruit crop ( apple)<br />

as apple trees deprive l<strong>and</strong> for alternative crops <strong>and</strong> make l<strong>and</strong> less fertile for other crops,<br />

when they are produced in the same area.<br />

Table 5.8: Relative Importance <strong>of</strong> Facton for Divenification towards <strong>Horticultural</strong><br />

<strong>Crops</strong><br />

Weighted MeaD CauliOower Apple<br />

Wei2bted Mean RIlIIk Wei2bted MeaD Rank<br />

Price 5.05 I 5.50 I<br />

Yield 4.87 2 3.40 4<br />

Irri2atioD availability 4.55 3 1.00 6<br />

Labour availability 3.53 4 4.95 2<br />

Food availability for<br />

consumption 1.70 5 4.05 3<br />

Credit availability 1.30 6 2.08 5<br />

Source: Pnmary data<br />

5.4. Source <strong>of</strong> Diversity in Area Response to Cauliflower Prices<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern can take any direction i.e., from low value to<br />

high value crops <strong>and</strong> vice versa. In tenos <strong>of</strong> high value horticultura1 crops, price change<br />

is dramatic <strong>and</strong> that too within a single season. Consequently, the overall supply elasticity<br />

<strong>of</strong> these crops could be generally low as compared to other crops. Due to lack <strong>of</strong> time<br />

series data under conditions <strong>of</strong> technological change <strong>and</strong> variable weather constitute a<br />

weak basis for estimating response behaviour <strong>and</strong> hence an alternative observation<br />

method is required (Medellin et aI., 1994), which is attempted here. Using three years<br />

data, farmen were classified on the basis <strong>of</strong> their response to price. There are three<br />

different group <strong>of</strong> farmers, i.e., farmers that responded positively to the change in prices<br />

(they increased/decreased area under the crop in the event <strong>of</strong> increase/decrease in the<br />

145


price <strong>of</strong> the crop), the group <strong>of</strong> fanners that responded perversely to the change in prices<br />

(they increased/decreased area under the crop in the event <strong>of</strong> decrease! increase in the<br />

price <strong>of</strong> the crop) <strong>and</strong> the group that did not responded to the change in prices (no change<br />

in area under the crop in the event <strong>of</strong> change in price).<br />

Several economic <strong>and</strong> non-economic factors ranging from farm, household to crop<br />

specific can influence such difference in response. The household, whose aggregate<br />

income is more dependent on one crop, is expected to respond readily to change in price<br />

as compared to the household to which the crop do not contribute much to the total<br />

household income. Since high value crops like cauliflower are characterized as highly<br />

resource <strong>and</strong> capital intensive, difference in supply response also could differ due to the<br />

typology <strong>of</strong> household in terms <strong>of</strong> human capital, resowce availability <strong>and</strong> access to<br />

credit etc. Prices <strong>of</strong> crops change every year <strong>and</strong> when the price <strong>of</strong> the crop increases,<br />

farmers' response to price becomes dependant on the availability <strong>of</strong> resources <strong>and</strong> access<br />

to credit. It is especially so because, in order to increase area under the high value crops,<br />

more labour <strong>and</strong> capital are needed. Increased area under the crop with insufficient labour<br />

can adversely affect the returns from the crop as these crops are highly perishable <strong>and</strong><br />

non-availability <strong>of</strong> sufficient labour at the time <strong>of</strong> harvesting <strong>and</strong> marketing can lead to<br />

enormous loss to the growers. In other words, farmers lacking resources may not able to<br />

respond to change in prices. There is a possibility that when the resource becomes scarce,<br />

farmers are forced to decrease the area under the crop even when price increase is<br />

anticipated. As the price <strong>and</strong> the production <strong>of</strong> high value crops fluctuate widely, some<br />

farmers <strong>of</strong>ten gains enormously in the event <strong>of</strong> getting most favourable market (price)<br />

<strong>and</strong> technology (yield) conditions. This results in their not readily responding to change<br />

in price. The whole set <strong>of</strong> linkages between economic <strong>and</strong> non-economic factors <strong>and</strong><br />

supply response shows that there is need to consider farm, household <strong>and</strong> crop specific<br />

factors that tend to collectively influence farmers' response pattern.<br />

The response <strong>of</strong> each participant is analyzed on the basis <strong>of</strong> an analysis <strong>of</strong> variance<br />

(ANOVA). Pair-wise comparison among the three groups <strong>of</strong> farmers is subsequently<br />

mfde using Tukey's test as the variables are continuous <strong>and</strong> not discrete in nature. The<br />

factors chosen include socio-economic characteristics like age <strong>and</strong> family size, farm-<br />

146


specific factors like farm size, annual income, disaster level <strong>of</strong> income 32 <strong>of</strong> the household,<br />

etc, resource-specific like irrigation, l<strong>and</strong> to labour ratio <strong>and</strong> crop-specific factors like<br />

productivity <strong>of</strong> the crop <strong>and</strong> the focused income 33 from cauliflower crop.<br />

The results indicate that the farmers who have responded positively to change in<br />

prices <strong>of</strong> cauliflower are young with an average age <strong>of</strong> 46 years, whereas those who<br />

responded perversely to the crop prices consist <strong>of</strong> old farmers who are generally more<br />

conservative (table 5.9). The disaster level <strong>of</strong> income <strong>of</strong> the farmers who responded<br />

positively to price is high despite having relatively less family members at home. But<br />

interestingly they also earn higher annual income from their farm <strong>and</strong> non-farm activities<br />

which helps them to respond positively to change in prices. High income enables them to<br />

take higher risk in the production decision <strong>and</strong> hire more resource at the time <strong>of</strong><br />

requirement. Additionally, the relatively proximity <strong>of</strong> their farm to road probably reduces<br />

the cost <strong>of</strong> selling the crop with less wastage during transportation. They also face lower<br />

resource constraints. Relatively low ratio <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> to agriCUltural labour indicates the<br />

availability <strong>of</strong> family labour; it helps them to be more flexible in responding to change in<br />

price, as they need not be dependent on hired labour for diverting the area under<br />

cauliflower, which is highly labour intensive crop. But, labour intensity in terms <strong>of</strong> man<br />

days per ha <strong>of</strong> these farmers is the lowest. High value <strong>of</strong> farm assets testify that farmers<br />

invest more on capital (capital-intensive) than on labour in the production <strong>of</strong> the crop.<br />

The farmers <strong>of</strong> this group are found to have achieved high productivity. Interestingly,<br />

they have higher average farm size which points to the link between farm size,<br />

productivity <strong>and</strong> supply response behaviour <strong>of</strong> farmers. Since farmers have to decide on<br />

the area allocation between a food or commercial crop, a guaranteed high income from<br />

commercial crop would indicate their choice in addition to liberating them consumption<br />

constraints <strong>and</strong> enable them to positively respond to higher price expectation from<br />

commercial crop.<br />

32 The disaster level <strong>of</strong> income is computed as d = MCN - OFI, where MCN is the minimum consumption<br />

requirements <strong>of</strong> the farm family plus other critical expenditures by the household during a year <strong>and</strong> OFI is<br />

the annual <strong>of</strong>f·farm income <strong>of</strong>farm household<br />

lJ Focused income is the mean value <strong>of</strong> the focused gain <strong>and</strong> focused loss. The focused gain is the net<br />

i~come <strong>of</strong> the farmers (income over paid-out cost) in a situation .when f~er gets the maximum p~ce <strong>and</strong><br />

maximum production together. Similarly, the net focused loss IS the net Income <strong>of</strong> the farmers (,"come<br />

OVer paid-out cost) in a situation when fanner gets the minimum income <strong>and</strong> mmlmum YIeld together.<br />

147


Ta bI e 59 . : A verage Val ueso fD escriptive Variables amon!! Cauliflower Growers<br />

No Response Positive Response Perverse Response<br />

Group (35) Group (16) . Group (9)<br />

Socio-EcODOmiC Factors<br />

Age (Years)a, < * 62.80 46.31<br />

Family Size (Numbers)<br />

6.66 6.44<br />

Farm-Specific Factors<br />

70A4<br />

7.00<br />

Farm Size (Ha) 2.37 4.18<br />

Percentage <strong>of</strong> area under<br />

cauliflower to GCA 50.87 52.10<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> Produced<br />

in a Year 3.94 4.75<br />

Annual Income (Rs.) < * 144745 165792<br />

Farm Assets (Rs.) 19117.14 20959.38<br />

Disastrous Income (Rs.) • * 55893 78915<br />

Labour Intensity (Man days<br />

I per hal 324.87 296.78<br />

Distance <strong>of</strong> farm to nearest<br />

road (Meters) • ** 308.14 163.75<br />

Resource-Specific Factors<br />

. L<strong>and</strong> to Labour Ratio' ** 0.3394 0.2294<br />

Irrigation Intensity (Net<br />

irrigated area/Net Cropped<br />

Area) 65.95 64.66<br />

Crop-Specific Factors<br />

Yield <strong>of</strong> the crop<br />

(ProductionlHa) a,b,< * 21254.02 26065.42<br />

! Focused Income from the<br />

! Crop (Rs.) 49340.40 86365.56<br />

• . .<br />

Indicates difference <strong>of</strong> no response group vIs positive response group<br />

b Indicates difference <strong>of</strong> no response group vis perverse response group<br />

C Indicates difference <strong>of</strong> positive response group vIs perverse no response group<br />

.. 1 % indicates significant level <strong>and</strong> .* indicates 5 % significant level<br />

Source: Primary data<br />

2.86<br />

56.00<br />

4.22<br />

84896<br />

18055.56<br />

102405<br />

308.15<br />

312.77<br />

0.4719<br />

73.88<br />

13314.23<br />

76224.53<br />

The farmers who did not respond to the change in prices (no response group) have<br />

the lowest average size <strong>of</strong> farm <strong>and</strong> they produced relatively less number <strong>of</strong> crops in a<br />

year. Since, they have low diversity in their cropping pattern; the aggregate risk in the<br />

farm production is higher for them. This substantiates their non-responsive behaviour.<br />

Ihterestingiy, these farmers do not have really high expectations about income from the<br />

148


crop, over a period <strong>of</strong> time, which is reflected in the lowest focused income from<br />

cauliflower crop. Since, productivity <strong>of</strong> the crop <strong>of</strong> these farmers is high, it could be<br />

possible that they received relatively low price from their produce that in turn reduced<br />

overall income from the crop. Their farms are relatively far away from the road <strong>and</strong><br />

market that reduces their market access advantage; it results in higher amount <strong>of</strong> wastage<br />

<strong>of</strong> the produce during transportation <strong>and</strong> marketing. In other words, lack <strong>of</strong> access to road<br />

inhibits their area supply response. They are risk-averse farmers as they have allocated<br />

lower share <strong>of</strong>l<strong>and</strong> to cauliflower.<br />

The farmers' perverse response to price is indicative <strong>of</strong> high food requirements at<br />

home coupled with low annual income. Both characteristics point to the high risk<br />

situation <strong>of</strong> these farmers in the event <strong>of</strong> unfavourable market <strong>and</strong> weather conditions.<br />

Higher food <strong>and</strong> other critical expenditure at home can be a reflection <strong>of</strong> the relatively<br />

bigger size <strong>of</strong> family. Low aggregate annual income 34 is either due to lack <strong>of</strong> non-farm<br />

income source or due to low l<strong>and</strong> productivity. It could be that these farmers realize the<br />

lowest productivity from the crop despite having the highest proportionate <strong>of</strong> area under<br />

irrigation. More importantly, their high l<strong>and</strong>-labour ratio indicates constraint <strong>of</strong> own<br />

resources for the production <strong>of</strong> cauliflower, which is a high labour intensive crop that<br />

require huge amount <strong>of</strong> labour not only for harvesting purposes but also for marketing the<br />

crop. As farmers mainly sell their produce in far-<strong>of</strong>f markets; therefore transport<br />

bottlenecks due to distance from road-head, lack <strong>of</strong> sufficient labour at the time <strong>of</strong><br />

marketing etc, be important factors for their perverse supply response. Since, this group is<br />

relatively poor due to low annual income <strong>and</strong> high consumption needs; they probably<br />

could not hire labour when increase in price <strong>of</strong> cauliflower is anticipated. This group <strong>of</strong><br />

farmers is usually headed by the old people. They experience the lowest crop productivity<br />

<strong>and</strong> in addition low resource base for investment <strong>and</strong> labour hiring propensity evidently<br />

affects the supply response behaviour <strong>of</strong> these farmers.<br />

34 Farm <strong>and</strong> non~fann activities<br />

149


5.5. Magnitude <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from Food <strong>Crops</strong> to<br />

<strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong><br />

The farmers do not differ only in terms <strong>of</strong> the nature <strong>and</strong> direction <strong>of</strong> shift in<br />

cropping pattern towards horticultural crops but also in terms <strong>of</strong> the magnitude <strong>of</strong> shift in<br />

area from food crops to horticultural crops. In this section, an overview <strong>of</strong> the socioeconomic<br />

characteristics <strong>of</strong> fanners at different levels <strong>of</strong> shift towards horticultural crops<br />

is outlined. In addition, the role <strong>of</strong> economic <strong>and</strong> non-economic factors is also examined.<br />

5.5.1. Socio Economic Features <strong>and</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

Socia-economic factors can exert significant influence on the typologies <strong>of</strong><br />

reallocation in cropping pattern through their influence on resource availability <strong>and</strong> risk<br />

management abilities at fann level. The results show that farmers who have shifted large<br />

share <strong>of</strong> area in favour <strong>of</strong> cauliflower have larger family size <strong>and</strong> more dependants (table<br />

5.1 0). In the case <strong>of</strong> apple, the magnitude <strong>of</strong> shift in area is inversely related to family<br />

size <strong>and</strong> dependants. Irrigation is found vital for reallocation decision towards<br />

cauliflower, but not for apple crop. However, there is similarity in the role <strong>of</strong> home in<br />

shifting area towards both the crops. Availability <strong>of</strong> more home labour, including wife<br />

<strong>and</strong> children significantly influences the extent <strong>of</strong> shift in the cropping pattern. Both<br />

crops are highly labour intensive <strong>and</strong> availability <strong>of</strong>labour has helped farmers to take the<br />

decisions <strong>of</strong> reallocating higher extent <strong>of</strong> area towards these crops.<br />

150


Table S.lO: Socio-Economic Characteristics at Different Levels <strong>of</strong> Shift in Cropping<br />

Pattern<br />

.<br />

Family Number <strong>of</strong> Farm Irrigation L<strong>and</strong>ILabour Annual<br />

Extent <strong>of</strong> Cropping size dependants size intensity** Non-farm<br />

I Pattern Shift" (No.) (No.) (ha) income<br />

CRs.)<br />

I C.nIIfIower Low 5.88 2.17 2.34 61.27 0.20 90673<br />

Medium 6.82 2.10 3.16 61.50 0.23 85484<br />

IIi2h 7.20 2.80 3.14 82.94 0.18 83127<br />

Apple Low 7.12 2.25 5.56 22.29 0.39 96300<br />

Medium 6.28 1.78 4.92 9.35 0.47 63875<br />

Hith 6.05 1.70 4.11 8.45 0.38 91100<br />

Note.<br />

i. • Extent <strong>of</strong> shift: For Low ·Iess than 10% shift in area under diversified crop <strong>of</strong>w.r.1. Net Cropped Area),<br />

Medium (\ 0-20% shift in area under diversified crop <strong>of</strong> w.r.1. Net Cropped Area) <strong>and</strong> High (More than<br />

30"10 shift in area under diversified crop <strong>of</strong>w.r.1. <strong>of</strong> Net Cropped Area)<br />

ii. *. Percentage <strong>of</strong> net irrigated area to net cropped area<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

5.5.2. Factors Influencing Decision <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> towards<br />

<strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong><br />

The micro level decision in tenns <strong>of</strong> shift <strong>of</strong> area in favour <strong>of</strong> high value crop is<br />

analyzed in tenns <strong>of</strong> level <strong>of</strong> substitution <strong>of</strong> food crop by high value horticultural crop.<br />

The farmers were asked as to when they initiated the major change in the cropping<br />

pattern in favour <strong>of</strong> high value crops, <strong>and</strong> what the extent <strong>of</strong> shift or substitution was in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> area <strong>and</strong> from which crops. They were further asked to give details <strong>of</strong> the price<br />

<strong>and</strong> yield <strong>of</strong> both the crops that were interchanged or substituted at the time <strong>of</strong> switch <strong>and</strong><br />

what influenced their decision <strong>of</strong> shift35. The rationale for using the price <strong>and</strong> yield as<br />

expected by farmers 36 is that prospective yield <strong>and</strong> price has a strong motivating force<br />

which in the long run is likely to affect their acreage planning (De, 2005). Since farmers<br />

have experienced major changes in their cropping pattern in different periods, it is<br />

important to do price adjustment <strong>and</strong> it is done by deflating the price <strong>of</strong> the crops.<br />

Consumer Price Index- Agricultura1 labourer (CPI-AL) measure is used for price<br />

3S In the short run, changes in price <strong>of</strong> the crops may not bring about a significant change in acreage under<br />

crops due to the particular nature <strong>of</strong> agricultural production <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation <strong>of</strong> high value crops is<br />

generally a long tenn decision by the farmers, especially in the case <strong>of</strong> a fruit crop.<br />

"According to Shackle (1949), fanners, while deciding about changing l<strong>and</strong> allocation among crops aTe<br />

c~ncerned with the consequence <strong>of</strong> the decision in. the ~utu~e. Since, the outcome I~ not known at the l~me<br />

ot taking the decision, farmer has to restore to ImagmatlOn <strong>of</strong> figure (expectatIOn) about the pOSSIble<br />

outcome.<br />

151


adjustment (the price <strong>of</strong> the crops is deflated by CPI-AL in order to arrive at the real<br />

price). Information regarding their socio-economic status <strong>and</strong> others factors are such as<br />

their education, farm size, irrigation, <strong>and</strong> food requirements are obtained. Regression<br />

analysis is used to gauge the factors affecting the extent <strong>of</strong> substitution by farmers while<br />

considering economic <strong>and</strong> non-economic factors as explanatory factors. The relative<br />

price <strong>and</strong> relative income are used as explanatory variables in order to test whether<br />

farmers care fOT only price or also the income in their crop substitution decisions. The<br />

results are outlined separately for apple <strong>and</strong> cauliflower in view <strong>of</strong> the difference in the<br />

nature <strong>of</strong> the crops. The specification <strong>of</strong> the equation is as follows<br />

Where,<br />

A,,2 -Ac.; is the shift in area from low value crop (C2) (Wheat or Maize) to high value<br />

crop (C.) (apple or cauliflower)<br />

PcllPc2 ; is the ratio <strong>of</strong> the real prices <strong>of</strong> the crops C. <strong>and</strong> C 2 (at which farmer made the<br />

area shift decision)<br />

I.:dIc2 ; is the ratio <strong>of</strong> the real income (gross returns per ha) <strong>of</strong> the crops C. <strong>and</strong> C2 (at<br />

which farmer made the area shift decision)<br />

lNF ; is the annual non-farm income (Rs.)<br />

IE ; is the education level <strong>of</strong> farmers<br />

Res (FS.IRRI); denotes farm size (in hal <strong>and</strong> irrigation (net irrigated area)<br />

Cons; is the level <strong>of</strong> annual food requirement <strong>of</strong> substituted crop at home (in Rs)<br />

152


Table S.I1: Factors Affecting Decision for <strong>Diversification</strong> towards <strong>Horticultural</strong><br />

C rops<br />

Area Shift as a Dependut In Favour <strong>of</strong> Cauliflower In Favour <strong>of</strong> ADDie<br />

Variable Coefficient Coefficient<br />

Constant -0.1 I I (.770 0.624 (1.589)<br />

Relative Price.JBs.JKg) -0.620 (.518 0.034 (.288)<br />

Relative Income (OutputIHa) 0.481 (7.098 • 0.579 2.058)··<br />

Education (Years) -0.037 (.980) -0.233 (2.138)··<br />

Farm Size (Ha) 0.610 (8.675)· 0.204 (1.379)<br />

Irrigation Intensity (Net 0.107 (2.926)·. 0.031 (0269)<br />

irrigated Area/Net Cropped<br />

Area)<br />

Non-Farm Income (Rs.) 0.028 (0.771) 0226 (2.022)··<br />

Food crop (Wbeat/Maize) -0.123 (3.071).· -0.011 (.095)<br />

requirements at bome iRs.)<br />

Note.<br />

i. Competing <strong>Crops</strong> for Cauliflower: Wheat; For Apple: Wheat & Maize<br />

ii. Figures in the Parenthesis are t-values<br />

iii. Cauliflower R2: 0.944 Adjusted R2 :0.933, N~60<br />

Apple R2: 0.448, Adjusted R2 :0.361 ,N~60<br />

iv. • <strong>and</strong> •• signifies level <strong>of</strong> significance at I % <strong>and</strong> 5 % respectively<br />

The results show that the relative income from the crop is positive <strong>and</strong> statistically<br />

significant in explaining the crop substitution decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers (table 5.11). The<br />

relative price variable has come out to be insignificant <strong>and</strong> even negative in the case <strong>of</strong><br />

cauliflower_ This illustrates that farmers generally calculate the aggregate gain from crop<br />

in their decision than referring only to the price <strong>of</strong> the crop. Their capacity to generate<br />

higher productivity along with the better market prospects together explains farmers'<br />

decision. In terms <strong>of</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> resources, irrigation <strong>and</strong> farm size are positive <strong>and</strong><br />

statistically significant for cauliflower growing farmers, whereas for apple growers, nonfarm<br />

income is found to be positive <strong>and</strong> statistically significant. It might be because<br />

cauliflower is primarily a water-intensive crop <strong>and</strong> it is critical to have more irrigation to<br />

increase the area under this crop. Additionally, both the resources i.e., irrigation <strong>and</strong> farm<br />

size affect productivity <strong>of</strong> cauliflower. Since, there is a gestation period in the cultivation<br />

<strong>of</strong> apple, farmers are more concerned about the availability <strong>of</strong> non-farm source <strong>of</strong> income<br />

during the gestation period, while taking decision <strong>of</strong> area shift in favour <strong>of</strong> the crop.<br />

Education has negative <strong>and</strong> significant impact on such decision-making by apple<br />

growers. As higher shift in favour <strong>of</strong> apple is directly linked with increasing level <strong>of</strong><br />

specialisation. Apple being a perennial <strong>and</strong> plantation crop; it deprives l<strong>and</strong> for<br />

cultivation <strong>of</strong> other crops. Educated farmers are concerned also about risk from the<br />

153


production <strong>of</strong> crop, <strong>and</strong> hence prefer to have higher level <strong>of</strong> diversity in their cropping<br />

pattern than being fully specialized in one crop. They were found to have more awareness<br />

about the trade-<strong>of</strong>f between risk <strong>and</strong> income, whereas uneducated farmers concentrate<br />

more on income optimization than worry about the risk situation. The food crop<br />

requirements impact the decision <strong>of</strong> substitution; it is negative in both the cases <strong>and</strong> also<br />

significant for the farmers growing cauliflower. It means that higher food requirements at<br />

home inhibited the extent <strong>of</strong> crop substitution decision <strong>of</strong> farmers. The income from<br />

cauliflower is low as compared to apple <strong>and</strong> once apple growers get a bumper crop <strong>and</strong><br />

good price, it would cover many years <strong>of</strong> food <strong>and</strong> farm expenditure at home for many<br />

years to come. Thus, cauliflower growers are relatively more cautious in substituting food<br />

crop to high value crop.<br />

5.6 Summary<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> towards horticultura1 crops is one <strong>of</strong> the vital components <strong>of</strong> growth<br />

<strong>of</strong> output in addition to area, productivity <strong>and</strong> price change. In the case <strong>of</strong> diversification<br />

<strong>of</strong> area among crops, the concerns pertain to shift in the area, direction <strong>of</strong> changing l<strong>and</strong><br />

allocation among crops, <strong>and</strong> magnitude <strong>of</strong> shift in area from one crop to another. The<br />

study captures all these dimensions <strong>of</strong> diversification.<br />

The typology <strong>of</strong> shift from low to high value horticultural crops shows that shift<br />

with respect to initial area was high by cauliflower growers, whereas shift with respect to<br />

net cultivated area was higher by apple growers. In the case <strong>of</strong> cauliflower, large farmers<br />

dominate the extent <strong>of</strong> shift followed by the category <strong>of</strong> marginal farmers. This shows<br />

that marginal farmers have been able to diversify to a great extent while maintaining<br />

relatively higher level <strong>of</strong> subsistence. In terms <strong>of</strong> food security concerns, majority <strong>of</strong> the<br />

farmers who diversified towards cauliflower were food-self-sufficient before change in<br />

cropping pattern. This is not the case for farmers who have diversified towards apple.<br />

This could be mainly because <strong>of</strong> relatively high returns from apple crop. Cauliflower <strong>and</strong><br />

apple growers are less responsive to the change in the prices <strong>of</strong> food grains in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

ranging their consumption level.<br />

154


Undoubtedly, price is the utmost important factor that governs decision making as it<br />

directly influences the income potential <strong>of</strong> the crop. But other non-economic factors are<br />

also significant in such decision-making <strong>and</strong> significance varies between vegetable crops<br />

<strong>and</strong> fruit crops. Labour availability <strong>and</strong> food production from the l<strong>and</strong> are more critical<br />

while diversifying from food to apple. Irrigation <strong>and</strong> productivity <strong>of</strong> the crop are more<br />

significant for farmers growing cauliflower primarily because <strong>of</strong> the water-intensive<br />

nature <strong>of</strong> cauliflower crop.<br />

Both fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables are high value crops that promise huge gains in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

output per ha, higher employment <strong>and</strong> farm income. However, there is a difference in the<br />

decision-making process <strong>of</strong> diversification towards these crops by farmers; it pertains to<br />

degree <strong>of</strong> flexibility in crop, relative returns <strong>of</strong> the crops <strong>and</strong> consequence <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification on the allocation pr<strong>of</strong>ile <strong>of</strong> the farmer 17 • Relative incomes <strong>of</strong> the crop<br />

determine the crop substitution decisions <strong>of</strong> fanners. This means that farmers calculate<br />

the aggregate gain from the crop than considering only the price <strong>of</strong> the crop. Their<br />

capacity to generate higher productivity along with better market prospects together<br />

explains farmers' decision. Thus, upgradation <strong>of</strong> technology <strong>and</strong> marketing facilities are<br />

concomitantly required; only harping on market improvement for increasing l<strong>and</strong> in<br />

favour <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops is not adequate. In the case <strong>of</strong> cauliflower, resource<br />

availability at farm level is more important for diversification decision, while availability<br />

<strong>of</strong> additional income source is found to be vital for apple growers. Interestingly,<br />

education is inversely related to the diversification decision <strong>of</strong> apple growers as such<br />

decisions are determined by the level <strong>of</strong> specialisation required due to it being a perennial<br />

or plantation crop. Educated farmers are concerned also about the risk from production <strong>of</strong><br />

crop <strong>and</strong> hence prefer to have higher level <strong>of</strong> diversity in their cropping pattern than<br />

being fully specialized in one crop.<br />

L<strong>and</strong> is more <strong>of</strong> an inelastic factor <strong>of</strong> production as compared to other resources<br />

including labour <strong>and</strong> capital. Additionally, l<strong>and</strong> allocation to fruit crop is inflexible as<br />

decision <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation to apple cannot be easily reversed due its being a plantation<br />

j h 'aI" I n1'k' f<br />

Higher exlenl <strong>of</strong> shift by apple growers are expected 10 make I em specl lze In app e, U 1 e In case 0<br />

cauliflower crop<br />

155


crop. Consequently, over a period <strong>of</strong> time, farmers face both risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty due to<br />

their decision <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation to high value crops. Thus, their aversion to both risk <strong>and</strong><br />

uncertainty are expected to influence their decision to stick to the prevailing pattern <strong>of</strong><br />

laod allocation to horticultural crops. The next chapter deals with examining the role <strong>of</strong><br />

both risk aod uncertainty in farmers' decision <strong>of</strong>l<strong>and</strong> allocation to horticultural crops.<br />

156


CHAPTER VI<br />

EXPECTATIONS, RISK ATTITUDES AND LAND<br />

ALLOCATION DECISIONS<br />

6.1. Introduction<br />

The decision <strong>of</strong>l<strong>and</strong> allocation among food <strong>and</strong> commercial crops is also one <strong>of</strong> the<br />

precautions which resource administrators or managers can use in adjusting to risky <strong>and</strong><br />

uncertainty situations (Heady, 1952). There are two aspects <strong>of</strong> planning pertaining to l<strong>and</strong><br />

allocation decisions that deal with risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty independently. One is the aspect<br />

<strong>of</strong> problem <strong>of</strong> planning under perfect knowledge, where the farmer is knowledgeable<br />

about the outcome <strong>of</strong> the decisions made; the other aspect deals with the planning under<br />

imperfect knowledge, wherein the aim <strong>of</strong> the decision-maker is to minimize the variance<br />

<strong>of</strong> outcome, or prevent the occurrences <strong>of</strong> undesirable outcomes. In the situation <strong>of</strong><br />

imperfect knowledge, farmer may attempt to combine food <strong>and</strong> commercial crops in such<br />

a manner as to minimize the probability <strong>of</strong> income dropping below levels required to<br />

meet family living expenses, farm costs <strong>and</strong> principal payments (Boussard <strong>and</strong> Petit,<br />

I 967).<br />

Farmers take production decisions in a largely uncertain environment, where the<br />

outcomes <strong>of</strong> the decisions could have large subjective probabilities. The motivation for<br />

higher allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> in favour <strong>of</strong> high value crops is driven due to desire <strong>of</strong><br />

generating high income, productivity <strong>and</strong> employment. Fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables are highly<br />

remunerative crops but are also considered as risky crops. The major feature <strong>of</strong><br />

horticultural crops is that the prices <strong>of</strong> crops fluctuate widely even within a single season.<br />

Lack <strong>of</strong> any support price <strong>and</strong> high perishability <strong>of</strong> the crops make the horticultural<br />

growers even more vulnerable to risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty than growers <strong>of</strong> other high value<br />

crops like rice or sugarcane. In the event <strong>of</strong> greater extent <strong>of</strong> risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty, the<br />

kportance <strong>of</strong> the same is high for the farmers while taking l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions.<br />

157


At the farm level, the concept <strong>of</strong> expectation is generally used in terms <strong>of</strong> a response<br />

to uncertainty involved in the production process. There are several ways in whi~h the<br />

information regarding expectation is obtained; such information pertains to the<br />

probability <strong>and</strong> possibility <strong>of</strong> different prices, incomes or events at the fann level.<br />

Specific questions here include: which price level is considered as most pr<strong>of</strong>itable by the<br />

farmer; what are the possibilities <strong>of</strong> different range <strong>of</strong> prices, what is the probability <strong>of</strong><br />

occurrences <strong>of</strong> different levels <strong>of</strong> prices; the price level that might surprise fanners, etc<br />

(Shackle, 1949; Williams, 1951; Binswanger; 1981 <strong>and</strong> Hardaker, 2(00). Expectation<br />

signifies the preferences <strong>and</strong> confidence levels <strong>of</strong> fanners in production <strong>of</strong> a particular<br />

crop <strong>and</strong> hence the resource allocation, including l<strong>and</strong>.<br />

Farmers tend to have expectations about different economic outcomes including<br />

price <strong>and</strong> yield, though available literature on the topic seems to lay more emphasis on<br />

the price expectations only. Price may not be the only factor in decision making;<br />

heterogeneity in resources <strong>and</strong> capital endowments <strong>of</strong> the fanners <strong>and</strong> access to input <strong>and</strong><br />

output market, all together affect the output <strong>and</strong> its variability. Difference in the level <strong>of</strong><br />

crop yields influences revenue directly <strong>and</strong> hence both price <strong>and</strong> output are important. It<br />

could be hypothesized that fanners with relatively higher level <strong>of</strong> crop productivity may<br />

allocate more l<strong>and</strong> to high value crop even at a low expected price. In this context, it is<br />

vital to examine the link between the price <strong>and</strong> income expectation in the l<strong>and</strong> allocation<br />

decisions by the fanners.<br />

Risk is also generally considered a strong behavioural force affecting decision<br />

making. There are several ways in which risk is measured. One aspect <strong>of</strong> risk relates to<br />

the variability in returns across time, which is a function <strong>of</strong> yearly changes in yield, crop<br />

prices <strong>and</strong> input costs 38 • The risk from the production <strong>of</strong> the crop can be decomposed into<br />

price <strong>and</strong> yield risk. Since, the nature <strong>of</strong> the fruit <strong>and</strong> vegetable crops is different, it is<br />

vital to evaluate the relative role <strong>of</strong> price <strong>and</strong> yield risk in the aggregate income risk<br />

independently. Another vital perspective <strong>of</strong> risk is how far <strong>and</strong> how <strong>of</strong>ten returns unable<br />

3, Since variance is taken as an indicator <strong>of</strong> variability. risk aversion is assumed to st<strong>and</strong> against departure<br />

rIbm the mean, even if income is rising. The est:mation <strong>of</strong> ri~k aversion is pure1y a subjective task <strong>and</strong> any<br />

chosen value is an extremely difficult task (Boussard <strong>and</strong> Petll, 1967).<br />

158


to reach a below mean level <strong>of</strong> return. Here, risk is considered as a cost in fanners'<br />

decision pertaining to l<strong>and</strong> allocation to high value crops (Rourn~t, 1976). The Safety­<br />

First principle (Roy, 1952) accounts for such costs in analyzing fanners' behaviour<br />

towards risk. Here, fanners are preoccupied not with the objective <strong>of</strong> maximizing income<br />

but with maximizing their chances <strong>of</strong> survival. Decisions <strong>of</strong> fanners do not wholly<br />

depend on their attitudes towards risk, but also on the differences in their subjective<br />

needs, <strong>and</strong> resource endowments (Shahaduddin et al. 1986).<br />

Due to fluctuation in the components <strong>of</strong> revenue from the crop, one can visualise<br />

two groups <strong>of</strong> fanners: the first group <strong>of</strong> fanners would prefer to be on the safe side <strong>and</strong><br />

hence their allocation decisions are explained by the income <strong>and</strong> yield variance <strong>of</strong> their<br />

crop as compared to the disaster level <strong>of</strong> income <strong>of</strong> the farm household. The second<br />

group constitutes farmers who prefer to take risk in their l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions. Here,<br />

fanners are risk-takers as their disaster level <strong>of</strong> income remains higher than the mean<br />

income from the crop produced for commercial purpose 39 • Risk taking behaviour in the<br />

production <strong>of</strong> high value crop like horticultural crops could be generic due to two<br />

reasons; the first reason is that the decision <strong>of</strong> allocation is generally based on<br />

expectations about the future outcomes <strong>and</strong> hence farmers tend to operate under<br />

imperfect knowledge. Here, they take their production decision in an uncertain<br />

environment (William, 1952). When the actual results deviate from the anticipated<br />

harvest outcomes, fanners tend to bear the risk <strong>of</strong> both income <strong>and</strong> consumption, as they<br />

have allocated l<strong>and</strong> to a commercial crop against food crop. Second, due to the existence<br />

<strong>of</strong> huge b<strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> price <strong>and</strong> yield, there could be high fluctuations in the revenue. Not only<br />

rich fanners but also the poor farmers take risk to reduce poverty (Kunreuther <strong>and</strong><br />

Wright, 1979). The farmers take risk by increasing the allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> in favour <strong>of</strong><br />

high value crop against the subsistence crop <strong>and</strong> take the risk about their food<br />

consumption <strong>and</strong> the ability <strong>of</strong> meeting other needs at home like education <strong>of</strong> children.<br />

But, not all farmers prefer to take such risk; instead they keep their l<strong>and</strong> allocation low in<br />

favour <strong>of</strong> commercial or high value crops. They follow the principle <strong>of</strong> Safety-First as<br />

~!} Such cases are prominent when one crop is the major source <strong>of</strong> farm income.<br />

159


they realize low utility from the production <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops. This <strong>of</strong>ten results in<br />

selection <strong>of</strong> low-risk crops rather than making jUgher allocation to horticultural crops.<br />

In this context, it is important to analyse the dynamics <strong>of</strong> price expectation at the<br />

farm level, its relation with crops' productivity, income <strong>and</strong> cost. For this purpose, we<br />

obtained the price expectations <strong>of</strong> fanners <strong>and</strong> the same are compared with the empirical<br />

observations on horticultural crops. Then, the price expectations by the farmers are linked<br />

with their input-use propensities <strong>and</strong> income, productivity <strong>and</strong> cost outcomes. In the next<br />

section, the relative role <strong>of</strong> price <strong>and</strong> yield risk in the aggregate income risk faced by the<br />

farmers producing fruit <strong>and</strong> vegetable crops are presented. We then examined the risk<br />

attitudes <strong>of</strong> the farmers <strong>and</strong> its detenninant factors. Fanners are grouped on the basis <strong>of</strong><br />

their risk attitudes under the Safety-First framework, <strong>and</strong> factors behind their risk attitude<br />

are identified. Finally, we present the typology <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation <strong>and</strong> analysis <strong>of</strong> the role<br />

<strong>of</strong> expectation <strong>and</strong> risk related factors in production decisions by the farmers.<br />

6.2. Price Expectations at Farm Level<br />

Economic decision theory recognizes the importance <strong>of</strong> decision makers'<br />

expectations about future events <strong>and</strong> these expectations are <strong>of</strong>ten expressed as subjective<br />

probability distributions (Grisley <strong>and</strong> Kellogg, 1983). Here, fanners' expected outcomes<br />

about price <strong>and</strong> yield are elicited. Then, a comparison is attempted between the<br />

expectations <strong>and</strong> actual harvest results.<br />

6.2.1. Dynamics <strong>of</strong> Price Expectations<br />

Fanners take their decisions in an uncertain environment, therefore expected value<br />

<strong>of</strong> returns <strong>and</strong> its variability has to be accounted for (Nowshirvani, 1971). Farmers tend to<br />

build expectations about the outcome <strong>of</strong> income, pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>and</strong> risk pattern, which are<br />

based on their past experiences <strong>of</strong> different ranges <strong>of</strong> outcomes in terms <strong>of</strong> price, <strong>and</strong><br />

yield. Therefore, before obtaining price expectations from farmers, we had to obtain their<br />

experience <strong>of</strong> the minimum <strong>and</strong> maximum prices <strong>and</strong> production <strong>of</strong> the selected<br />

160


horticultural crop4(). This information was collected to ensure that expectation <strong>of</strong> the price<br />

<strong>and</strong> production by them cO!Des within the b<strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> maximum <strong>and</strong> minimum prices <strong>and</strong><br />

production. Then, the question was asked about the most expected price <strong>and</strong> production<br />

<strong>of</strong> the crop that might have influenced them to take the decision. In addition, the data on<br />

area, price <strong>and</strong> production in the last three years was obtained. The input-wise cost data<br />

was collected to fmd various types <strong>of</strong> costs incurred by the farmers (fixed, variable, paidout,<br />

production, marketing cost etc.).<br />

Data on price expectations <strong>of</strong> cau1if1ower growers illustrates that majority <strong>of</strong> the<br />

farmers expected a price <strong>of</strong> Rs. 10 per kg, though the b<strong>and</strong> varied from Rs.6 to Rs.l5 per<br />

kg (table 6.1)41. The average value <strong>of</strong> the expected price <strong>of</strong> cauliflower is Rs. 9.89 per kg.<br />

The price expectation by twenty-two <strong>of</strong> the farmers was less than the average value,<br />

while price expectation <strong>of</strong> eleven <strong>of</strong> the farmers was greater than Rs 9.89 per kg. The<br />

range <strong>of</strong> minimum price varied from Rs.2 to Rs 9.5 per kg <strong>and</strong> Rs.5.5 per kg is its mean<br />

value. In terms <strong>of</strong> maximum price, the mean price is Rs. 14.25 per kg. But, thirty eight <strong>of</strong><br />

the farmers were not able to get this price for the produce, which shows only a few<br />

fanners were able to realize a favourable price. In the case <strong>of</strong> apple, the average value <strong>of</strong><br />

the expected, minimum <strong>and</strong> maximum price was Rs 17.50, Rs 10.20 <strong>and</strong> Rs 25.60 per kg<br />

respectively. Also, large number <strong>of</strong> farmers growing apple never realized high price for<br />

their produce. At the same time, many <strong>of</strong> them received price that was far below the<br />

average value <strong>of</strong> the minimum price <strong>of</strong> the crop. This means that majority <strong>of</strong> the apple<br />

growers experienced low or unfavourable prices. Relatively, the maximum price <strong>of</strong> apple<br />

is far higher than the cauliflower price. In terms <strong>of</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> cauliflower <strong>and</strong> apple, only a<br />

few farmers were able to realize the most favourable price <strong>of</strong> the crop, pointing to<br />

variance in returns accrued in marketing.<br />

" 'Good <strong>and</strong> bad years' in the produclion <strong>and</strong> price is a general feature <strong>of</strong> agricultural sector, especially in<br />

1eVeioping countries <strong>and</strong> this also influences the revenue from the crop. '"<br />

The detailed picture <strong>of</strong> price expectation! by cauliflower <strong>and</strong> apple growers are proVJded 10 appendIX 6.1<br />

<strong>and</strong> 6.2<br />

161


Table 61 . . F armers Experience with Price <strong>of</strong> Cauliflower <strong>and</strong> Apple (Rs.lk2)<br />

Range <strong>of</strong> Frequency* Range <strong>of</strong> Frequency Range <strong>of</strong> FrequeD


gestation period in the production <strong>of</strong> apple crop <strong>and</strong> difference in the age <strong>of</strong> trees across<br />

different farmers.<br />

Table 6.2: Comparison <strong>of</strong> Actual Results <strong>and</strong> Farmers' Expected Values <strong>of</strong> Selected<br />

Distributions<br />

Below·20% ·20 to ·10% ·10% to 0% o to 10% 10-20% Above 20%<br />

Cauliflower 6 2 8 21 13 10<br />

Price<br />

Cauliflower 4 0 5 6 11 34<br />

Yield<br />

Apple Price 0 3 8 20 16 13<br />

Apple Yield 21 4 7 9 13 6<br />

Note.<br />

i. The units are the number <strong>of</strong> sampled farmers <strong>and</strong> the figures show the number <strong>of</strong> farmers who received<br />

actual values <strong>of</strong> economic outcome (price <strong>and</strong> yields) that were within each percent interval above or below<br />

their expected value <strong>of</strong> the same variable. For each category there are 60 farmers<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

6.2.2. Relation <strong>of</strong> Price Expectations with Other Economic<br />

Factors<br />

According to economic theory, price expectation is likely to exert a strong influence<br />

on the behaviour <strong>of</strong> farmers regarding resource allocation, including inputs like l<strong>and</strong>,<br />

labour <strong>and</strong> capital (Williams, 1951, Roy, 1952, <strong>and</strong> Medellin et aI. 1994). Generally,<br />

farmers who expect a better price are likely to engage in more resource intensiveness as<br />

compared to others. Here, the influence <strong>of</strong> price expectation on the input-use propensities<br />

<strong>of</strong> the farmers which affects the economic outcomes in terms <strong>of</strong> productivity <strong>and</strong> income<br />

was analysed. Then, the factors that influenced the price expectations by the farmers were<br />

identified.<br />

The input propensities <strong>of</strong> farmers growing cauliflower crop show that higher price<br />

expectations did not intensify either irrigation or labour 43 by farmers (table 6.3).<br />

Irrigation is generally restricted by the availability <strong>of</strong> water in the farm. However, the<br />

fanners with higher price expectations hire high amount <strong>of</strong> labour <strong>and</strong> are also more<br />

willing to pay high wages for the same. Majority <strong>of</strong> them are willing to reinvest their<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>its on l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> other crop related activities. When the total cost <strong>of</strong> production <strong>and</strong><br />

paid out cost by the farmers were compared, it turned out that for the farmers with higher<br />

I<br />

" This includes total home <strong>and</strong> hired lahour used for the selected crop<br />

163


price expectations, the total cost <strong>of</strong> production was less than those fanners whose price<br />

expectations was lower. But, the paid out cost which includes the cost <strong>of</strong> fertilizer,<br />

irrigation, labour hiring <strong>and</strong> use <strong>of</strong> chemical spray etc. <strong>of</strong> the fanners <strong>of</strong> this group was<br />

highest among the three groups. The lower total cost <strong>of</strong> production is probably due to<br />

factors like higher depreciation <strong>of</strong> farm assets, greater value <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong>, etc. In the case <strong>of</strong><br />

apple crop, the fanners with higher price expectations have higher extent <strong>of</strong> labour<br />

intensity <strong>and</strong> they hire more labour for carrying out production <strong>and</strong> marketing activities.<br />

Again, they are more willing to pay for labour <strong>and</strong> are more willing to reinvest their<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>it in the crop-related activities. The results for both cauliflower <strong>and</strong> apple crop<br />

illustrates that price expectations are vital for the input-use propensities <strong>of</strong> fanners. In<br />

other words, better expectations about the price influences the propensity to involve in<br />

more <strong>and</strong> better use <strong>of</strong> inputs.<br />

Table 6.3: Input Use Propensities <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> crop Growen According to Different<br />

p' nce E xpecta ti ons<br />

Cauliflower<br />

Apple<br />

Price expect.tioD Below Me.n Around Mean Above Mean Below Meln Around<br />

(N=22) (N=27) (N=1l) (N=28) MUD<br />

~lS)<br />

Irrigation IntemilI" 71.47 64.67 62.65 13.05 12.46<br />

Labour Intensity (Man- 302.21 . 339.38 280.05 192.41 197.37<br />

days per bal<br />

Percentage <strong>of</strong> 23.18 24.07 2955 49.21 40.67<br />

housebolds<br />

hiring<br />

labour for farm<br />

I purposes<br />

Percentage <strong>of</strong> farmen 45.45 40.74 5454 64.28 60.00<br />

I willing to pay higb for<br />

, labour hirinl!<br />

Paid out cost (lb. Per b. 73895 85512 80396 392.00 374.00<br />

or Rs. per plant)<br />

i Total cost (Rs. Per ha or 115074 128832 119634 480.00 472.00<br />

Rs. per plant)<br />

I Mean Crop Output 43823 49176 58603 268252 178051<br />

(2004-06) (lb.)<br />

I Percentage <strong>of</strong> farmen 50.00 62.22 63.60 53.55 66.66<br />

I willingness to reinvest<br />

i pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

! Share <strong>of</strong> are. under tbe 53.20 50.70 52.63 71.24 71.87<br />

: selected crop to GCA<br />

1. The cost for cauliflower IS III Rs. Per hectare basts, whereas the cost for apple crop IS gJven In Rs. per plant<br />

ii .• Percentage <strong>of</strong> net irrigated area to net cropped area<br />

~i .. N for each category is 60<br />

Source: Primary data<br />

Above<br />

Mean<br />

~=!7l<br />

5.55<br />

235.61<br />

75.00<br />

88.23<br />

483.00<br />

558.00<br />

345451<br />

70.55<br />

69.23<br />

164


Both economic <strong>and</strong> non-economic factors are considered in identifying variables<br />

that influence price expectations <strong>of</strong> fanners. The results are presented in table 6.4. It is<br />

clear from the results that price expectation by fanners is greatly influenced by their past<br />

experience with the range <strong>of</strong> prices. Fanners, within the group in which the expected<br />

price is higher than the mean expected price, experienced high price as compared to<br />

farmers <strong>of</strong> other groups. The average maximum price realized by these fanners is Rs<br />

17.50 <strong>and</strong> Rs. 28.47 per kg for cauliflower <strong>and</strong> apple respectively. At the same time,<br />

farmers with higher price expectation did not experience very low price for the crop,<br />

which was Rs. 10.65 <strong>and</strong> Rs. 5.36 per kg for apple <strong>and</strong> cauliflower respectively in<br />

comparison to Rs. 8.75 <strong>and</strong> Rs. 5.01 per kg for farmers with low price expectation.<br />

Interestingly, the farmers with higher price expectation have lower yield expectation in<br />

the case <strong>of</strong> cauliflower, but not for apple. This presents a paradox in the decision-making<br />

<strong>of</strong> fanners regarding fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetable crops. In terms <strong>of</strong> socio-economic<br />

characteristics, fanners having high expectations are young <strong>and</strong> more educated in case <strong>of</strong><br />

both apple <strong>and</strong> cauliflower. Their household is mainly headed by male members <strong>and</strong> they<br />

have higher fann size. This confirms that higher level <strong>of</strong> production helps in getting good<br />

price on account <strong>of</strong> the better bargaining power in the market.<br />

165


T a bl e 64 . . F actors E ~) PlalDlDl! I" P rice Expectations <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> crop Growers<br />

CaoliRo"er<br />

Apple<br />

Priceexpectatioa Below meaD ArouadMean Above mean Below mean Around Above<br />

(N=22) (N=27) (N=Il) (N=28) Mean mean<br />

(IS) (N~ 17)<br />

Minimum Priee 5.01 6.14 5.36 8.75 12.41 10.65<br />

Maximum price 13.17 13.77 17.50 24.46 24.81 28.47<br />

Expected Yield 14650 15689 14256 37.27 34.36 43.20<br />

(production per ha or<br />

Jll!r plant)<br />

Average value <strong>of</strong> 54904 61520 84165 122514 115908 252817<br />

maximum <strong>and</strong><br />

minimum income over<br />

paid out cost (RI.)<br />

Distance <strong>of</strong> farm from 371.59 182.04 277.27 448.21 328.00 417.06<br />

main road (m)<br />

Age <strong>of</strong> the Household 60.50 61.56 52.64 61.64 62.53 59.71<br />

Head (years)<br />

Education <strong>of</strong> tb. 50.00 51.85 81.82 53.57 66.67 70.59<br />

Household Head<br />

(Number <strong>of</strong> bousebold<br />

beaded by illiterate)<br />

Sex <strong>of</strong> tbe Household 86.36 70.37 81.82 71.43 86.67 70.59<br />

Head (penentage <strong>of</strong><br />

Households headed by<br />

Male)<br />

Firm Size (ba) 2.90 2.80 3.28 5.06 3.72 5.10<br />

.. . .<br />

Note. The YIeld for caulIflower IS m per hectare basIs, whereas the YIeld for apple crop IS gIVen m ProductIOn per plant<br />

Source: Primary data<br />

6.3. Relative Role <strong>of</strong> Price <strong>and</strong> Yield Risk in Fruits <strong>and</strong><br />

Vegetables<br />

Fanner faces two types <strong>of</strong> risk in his revenue from the crop, i.e., pnce <strong>and</strong><br />

production. The variability in both together explains the crop revenue risk. The revenue<br />

risk for apple <strong>and</strong> cauliflower is decomposed separately mainly because the difference in<br />

the nature <strong>of</strong> the crops lies broadly in terms <strong>of</strong> the gestation period <strong>of</strong> production <strong>and</strong><br />

marketing options which in tum influences the significance <strong>of</strong> prices <strong>and</strong> yield risk.<br />

Cauliflower is an annual crop <strong>and</strong> the decision <strong>of</strong> area allocation is very flexible in the<br />

sense that every year farmer can think <strong>of</strong> changing the area under the crop. In apple, there<br />

is a gestation period in production <strong>of</strong> 5·7 years initially, only after which fanners start<br />

getting returns <strong>and</strong> only after 12·15 years <strong>of</strong> planting, farmers get higher level <strong>of</strong> yield<br />

\from the crop. The decision here is inflexible, unlike vegetable crops, <strong>and</strong> it is not easy to<br />

reallocate l<strong>and</strong> to other crops in the same l<strong>and</strong>, where apple plantation exists. Fruit crop<br />

166


(apple) is relatively less perishable as compared to vegetable crop (cauliflower) <strong>and</strong> there<br />

are more marketing opportunities for the fruit crop. Due to high perishability <strong>of</strong> vegetable<br />

crop, fanners in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> are not able to sell their crop beyond Delhi market,<br />

whereas apple growers are able to sell in far away markets like Calcutta <strong>and</strong> Bangalore.<br />

Apple growers are able to hold their crop in the farm <strong>and</strong> also in the markets in order to<br />

wait for a better price. This improves their bargaining power in selling the crop at higher<br />

prices. Vegetable growing farmers on the other h<strong>and</strong> cannot hold their crop in the field<br />

<strong>and</strong> once they take their produce to the major market like Delhi, they cannot either hold<br />

back the produce or move to any other market. This bestows to poor bargaining power to<br />

the vegetable crop growers in comparison to the higher bargaining power <strong>of</strong> fruit crop<br />

growers. These differences in the production <strong>and</strong> marketing <strong>of</strong> the crops highlight the<br />

disparity associated with the risk <strong>of</strong> price <strong>and</strong> production as also the correlation between<br />

price <strong>and</strong> production <strong>of</strong> the crop.<br />

In order to identify the relative importance <strong>of</strong> price <strong>and</strong> production risk, the gross<br />

revenue variability is decomposed into price, yield <strong>and</strong> price-yield interaction<br />

components as provided by Barab <strong>and</strong> Binswanger (1982)44. If P is price, y is the yield<br />

<strong>and</strong> R is the gross revenue, the R =<br />

approximated as<br />

py <strong>and</strong> the variance <strong>of</strong> gross revenue can be<br />

Var (R) = y2 Var (P) + p2 Var(y) + 2y.p Cov (p,q)<br />

Where Var is the variance operator, p <strong>and</strong> y are the mean value <strong>of</strong> price <strong>and</strong> yield<br />

respectively <strong>and</strong> Cov is the covariance operator. Thus, the above identity splits variance<br />

<strong>of</strong> gross revenue into a price component (the fITSt term), <strong>and</strong> yield component (the second<br />

term) <strong>and</strong> a price-yield interaction component (the third term). The above identity can be<br />

used to compute the proportion <strong>of</strong> variability in gross revenue that is due to its individual<br />

components by rewriting it as<br />

i" The discussion <strong>of</strong> B",",,!, <strong>and</strong> Binswanger's work is substantially drawn from Walker <strong>and</strong> Ryan (1990) as<br />

\heJr paper is cited as a diSCUSSion paper CIrculated m international <strong>Crops</strong> Research InstJtute for Semi-Arid<br />

Tropics (ICRlSAT) <strong>and</strong> it is therefore unpublished.<br />

167


1= Y 2 Var (p) + p2 Var (y) + 2y.p Cov (p.g)<br />

Var(R) Var(R) Var(R)<br />

where the fIrst term is the contribution <strong>of</strong> price, the second tenn the contribution <strong>of</strong><br />

yield <strong>and</strong> the third term the contribution <strong>of</strong> the interaction term to revenue variability. By<br />

multiplying both sides <strong>of</strong> the above equation by 100, the contribution <strong>of</strong> the price, yield<br />

<strong>and</strong> interaction terms can be expressed in tenns <strong>of</strong> percentages. If the sum <strong>of</strong> the price<br />

<strong>and</strong> yield terms exceeds 100"10, it means that the price-yield interaction is negative<br />

because <strong>of</strong> negative correlation.<br />

By using the data 45 on prices <strong>and</strong> production levels <strong>of</strong> the selected horticultural<br />

crops, the revenue from the crop is decomposed into the price, yield <strong>and</strong> their interaction.<br />

The results <strong>of</strong> risk decomposition are summari2ed in table 6.5.<br />

T bl 65 -D<br />

ecomposl ·ti ono fI ncome Ri s kf rom A lPI e an de au lifl owe r<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> times Price risk less Price risk greater Negative<br />

than yield risk than )'ield risk interaction<br />

Apple 52 8 40<br />

Cauliflower 28 32 18<br />

Note:<br />

i. The units are the number <strong>of</strong> sampled farmers. The first two columns would add to 60.<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

a e . .<br />

A stark difference in found between apple <strong>and</strong> cauliflower. 52 <strong>of</strong> the 60 apple<br />

growing farmers experiences high variability in yield <strong>of</strong> the crop as compared to<br />

variability in price, whereas majority <strong>of</strong> the fanners growing cauliflower experiences<br />

high price variability than yield (32 out <strong>of</strong> 60). The negative interactions indicate that<br />

prices <strong>and</strong> yields are negatively covariate. The negative correlation between prices <strong>and</strong><br />

yields reduces crop revenue fluctuations <strong>and</strong> provides a natural hedge to farmers. This<br />

suggests the possibility that perfect price stabilization could destabilize income for some<br />

farmers (Ramaswami et ai, 2004). This would happen if the 'yield' component is greater<br />

than the sum <strong>of</strong> 'price' <strong>and</strong> the price·yield interaction components. Higher chance <strong>of</strong> this<br />

means larger is the negative correlation between price <strong>and</strong> yield. Indeed, when the price<br />

lerm <strong>and</strong> the price-yield inleraction term is set 10 zero (as would be the case with perfect<br />

1------<br />

" Three years (2004, 2005 <strong>and</strong> 2006) fann level data is obtained from the farmers on the price <strong>and</strong><br />

production levels.<br />

168


price stabilization), the variability <strong>of</strong> crop revenues increases in the case <strong>of</strong> 40 apple<br />

growing farmers as against 18 cauliflower growers. Thus, the major beneficiaries <strong>of</strong><br />

reduced price variability are the cauliflower growers <strong>and</strong> not apple growers. Stabilizing<br />

yield <strong>of</strong> the crop would be much more effective in stabilizing revenues <strong>of</strong> apple whereas<br />

stabilizing price, on the other h<strong>and</strong>, would be a more effective strategy to reduce revenue<br />

risk <strong>of</strong> cauliflower.<br />

The correlation between production <strong>and</strong> price provides a picture <strong>of</strong> difference in<br />

the nature <strong>of</strong> marketing <strong>of</strong> these crops. Table 6.6 indicates a positive <strong>and</strong> significant<br />

correlation between price <strong>and</strong> production for apple, whereas same is negative for<br />

cauliflower. It means apple growers who received higher level <strong>of</strong> production have been<br />

able to receive higher price <strong>of</strong> the crop. This is mainly because they are able to sell the<br />

produce in different forms <strong>and</strong> at different locations including Delhi, Calcutta <strong>and</strong><br />

Bangalore. Lack <strong>of</strong> such opportunity in vegetable market results in negative correlation<br />

between production <strong>and</strong> price. Farmers with higher produce <strong>of</strong> cauliflower also did not<br />

receive higher price. The correlation between the variability in price <strong>and</strong> production<br />

illustrates that cauliflower growers experienced a positive correlation between the<br />

variability <strong>of</strong> production <strong>and</strong> price, whereas this is not the case for apple. Vegetable is a<br />

more perishable crop with fewer opportunities in terms <strong>of</strong> scope <strong>of</strong> marketing.<br />

T able 6.6: Correlation between Production <strong>and</strong> Pnce 0 fA<br />

Correlation Mean Price <strong>and</strong><br />

CV in price <strong>and</strong><br />

Coefficient • production<br />

production<br />

Apple<br />

0.317'<br />

-0.287'<br />

Cauliflower<br />

• I % level <strong>of</strong> slgmficance<br />

** 5% level <strong>of</strong> significance<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

·0.111<br />

0.462""<br />

~pple an<br />

d Cauliflower, 2004-06<br />

6.4. Typology <strong>and</strong> Determinants <strong>of</strong> Risk Attitudes <strong>of</strong> Farmers<br />

Risk is one <strong>of</strong> the major characteristics in the farming sector. Primarily, there are<br />

three types <strong>of</strong> risk, i.e., risk as variable outcome, risk as unexpected, <strong>and</strong> risk as uncertain<br />

¥Iardaker, 2000). In the first definition, risk is generally calculated by measures such as<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation or coefficient <strong>of</strong> variation <strong>of</strong> outcome including price, yield or income.<br />

169


In the second definition <strong>of</strong> risk, risk is considered on the basis <strong>of</strong> chance <strong>of</strong> a bad<br />

outcome. Here, risk attitudes <strong>and</strong> behaviour <strong>of</strong> the farmelS are e~amined through different<br />

methods 46 • Earlier studies were based on eliciting risk attitudes <strong>of</strong> the farmers <strong>and</strong><br />

initially most <strong>of</strong> the research depended on subjective probabilities to explain farmers'<br />

behaviour. Shackle (1949) criticized the probability analysis on the basis that farmers are<br />

seldom aware <strong>of</strong> the probability <strong>of</strong> outcome. He put forth a system <strong>of</strong> potential surprise<br />

<strong>and</strong> focused on a loss function that indexes the extent to which a given gain/loss <strong>and</strong><br />

surprise combination "stimulates the mind". In addition to Shackle's contribution, the<br />

downside risk <strong>and</strong> the Safety-First principle drove attention <strong>of</strong> studies dealing with l<strong>and</strong><br />

allocation decisions by farmelS.<br />

All for the third deftnition <strong>of</strong> risk, where it is dermed as uncertainty <strong>of</strong> outcome,<br />

there are studies that used relative preferences <strong>of</strong> the outcome 47. In some situations,<br />

farmers were quizzed about the premium that measures how much a farmer is ready to<br />

forgo for some speciftc level <strong>of</strong> price <strong>and</strong> so on. Here, the degree <strong>of</strong> risk avelSion is the<br />

amount an individual is willing to pay to avoid participation in a fair bet, or the risk<br />

premium (Young, 1979). Many <strong>of</strong> these analyses were based on the skills <strong>of</strong> the<br />

interviewer in obtaining the information <strong>and</strong> hence possible interviewer-biases made the<br />

findings less signiftcant. In addition, it is argued that the above studies were based on<br />

concepts like probability, expected value <strong>and</strong> binary comparison <strong>of</strong> lottery that might not<br />

be meaningful to the average farmer, <strong>and</strong> hence questions depending on these concepts<br />

hardly reveal the actual behaviour. Risk attitudes may not be unravelled by asking the<br />

farmers to reveal their risk attitudes or by an approach that attributes deviation from risk<br />

neutral optimism to risk preferences. Rather, the attitudes towards risk must be obtained<br />

from the institutional <strong>and</strong> social environment that farmer lives in, his wealth position, the<br />

credit available to him, his investment possibilities <strong>and</strong> so on (Roumasset, 1976). Such<br />

environment is important for analysing the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions by the farmers as<br />

" The major difference in the role <strong>of</strong> different types <strong>of</strong> risk in decision-making <strong>of</strong> farmers is that in the first<br />

case (risk as variability) farmers faces trade-<strong>of</strong>f between pr<strong>of</strong>it <strong>and</strong> vanance, whereas In case <strong>of</strong> latter two<br />

~efinitions (risk as a chance <strong>of</strong> bad o~tcome. ~r uncertainty <strong>of</strong> outcome). fanners faces trade-<strong>of</strong>f between<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>it <strong>and</strong> security in their l<strong>and</strong> allocation decISIons.<br />

47 Includes expected utility models, pay-ffs, be .. etc<br />

170


these decisions involve costs, especially when both prices <strong>and</strong> yield are subject to huge<br />

fluctuations.<br />

The Safety-First principal propounded by Roy in 1952 was one <strong>of</strong> the methods that<br />

factored in such costs in farmers' decision. The Safety-First principle lays emphasis on<br />

the role <strong>of</strong> downside risk in farmers' attitude towards risk. Here, decision makers are<br />

preoccupied not with maximising income, but with maximising their chances <strong>of</strong> survival.<br />

Different choices by farmers do not depend on differences in their attitudes towards risks,<br />

but on the differences in their subsistence needs, resource endowments <strong>and</strong> perceptions <strong>of</strong><br />

the riskiness among competing crops (Shahabuddin et al. 1986). Farmers face downside<br />

risk 48 in their income process <strong>and</strong> their aggregate income risk is important if it results in<br />

consumption fluctuations, especially when credit <strong>and</strong> insurance markets are absent. In<br />

such a situation, a possible strategy for households is to take low value crops even if it<br />

implies lower returns (Dercon, 1996). Differences in resource endowments, socioeconomic<br />

characteristics <strong>and</strong> access to market influence the overall risk attitudes <strong>of</strong> the<br />

farmers which in tum affect their gain <strong>and</strong> loss from the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions <strong>and</strong><br />

influence their allocation towards horticultural crops.<br />

In order to fmd the role <strong>of</strong> risk on production decisions, Roy's Safety-First<br />

coefficient is used. Roy's Safety-First principle incorporates into a resource allocation<br />

model yields the "efficiency" condition<br />

MFCi = p{ (oQt 10 Xi) + [(d-u,)1 cr,)] { Ocri I Xi)<br />

for the farm household, where pt <strong>and</strong> Qt are the expected price <strong>and</strong> output <strong>of</strong> crop<br />

i, Xi is the quantity <strong>of</strong> input i used, d is the farm's household disaster income, u, is the<br />

household's expected income <strong>and</strong> cr, is the variance <strong>of</strong> the household income. MFC is the<br />

marginal factor cost <strong>of</strong> input i. (Shahbuddin et aI. 1986).<br />

Under Roy's Safety Principle, the impact <strong>of</strong> risk on the decision-maker is given by<br />

the risk coefficient (RC) = (d-u,)/ cr,). The relative magnitude <strong>of</strong> the variables d <strong>and</strong> u<br />

ttermines whether the farm family is "forced to gamble" (d>u) or "allowed to trade<br />

48 An estimate <strong>of</strong> income to suffer a decline if the market <strong>and</strong> weather conditions tum bad<br />

171


expected return for reduced risk" (d


level data <strong>and</strong> not using district level data as the price differs dramatically across farmers.<br />

The inc,?me is defmed as the revenue over the paid out cost only, <strong>and</strong> is computed as<br />

3<br />

u= LPiQi-LW;Xi<br />

i =1<br />

where u is the mean income from the crop, Pi is the price <strong>of</strong> the crop in the i lb year (3<br />

years data is used i.e., 2004, 2005 <strong>and</strong> 2006), Qi is the quantity <strong>of</strong> the crop produced by<br />

the farmer in the i Ib year, Wi is the price <strong>of</strong> the input purchased by the farmer in the i lb<br />

year <strong>and</strong> Xi is the quantity <strong>of</strong> the input purchased by the fanner in the i lb year 50 • The<br />

variance <strong>of</strong> income is calculated by st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation <strong>of</strong> income or returns from the crop<br />

by using last three years.<br />

T a bl e 67 . . F requene D' Istn 'b ution . 0 fF armers on the Basis <strong>of</strong> Risk Attitudes<br />

Risk Coeffident Caulill.wer Apple<br />

Below-2 10.00 8.33<br />

- 210-1 8.33 28.33<br />

-1 to 0 20.00 30.00<br />

o to 1<br />

15.00 20.00<br />

1 to 2 25.00 8.33<br />

Above 2 21.67 5.00<br />

Note:<br />

i. Figures are in percmtage <strong>of</strong> farmers, where the number <strong>of</strong> farmers are 60 for each category<br />

Sou"",: Primary Data<br />

Based on the risk coefficient measure, results show that most <strong>of</strong> the cauliflower<br />

growing farmers are risk-takers than averse to risk (table 6.7). More than 61 percent <strong>of</strong><br />

the fanners growing cauliflower have a positive risk coefficient. This indicates that risktaking<br />

behaviour is displayed by many farm households in the production <strong>of</strong> cauliflower.<br />

However, for apple, most <strong>of</strong> farmers take a safety-fITSt position on the basis <strong>of</strong> their l<strong>and</strong><br />

allocation decision. Around 66 percent <strong>of</strong> the apple growing farmers have negative risk<br />

coefficient points their safe position. The difference in the disaster level <strong>of</strong> income <strong>and</strong><br />

crop income explains the risk behaviour <strong>of</strong> farmers. Hence, it is either higher food<br />

consumption requirements at home or low income from the crop that influence the value<br />

\0 Only the paid out cost for both the production <strong>and</strong> marketing <strong>of</strong> crop is accounted for as farmers need to<br />

pay money/cash for it.<br />

173


<strong>of</strong> the risk coefficient. The socio-economic conditions including access to non-farm<br />

income source, farm size etc may also affect the risk behaviour <strong>of</strong> the farmers.<br />

In order to examine the role <strong>of</strong> socio-economic factors that influence risk behaviour<br />

<strong>of</strong> the farmers, a regression model is used with risk coefficient as the dependant variable.<br />

Independent factors include household-specific factors like age, family size, gender,<br />

access to credit, non-farm income <strong>and</strong> farm-specific factors including farm size, farm<br />

assets etc. The results are presented for cauliflower <strong>and</strong> apple growing farmers separately<br />

<strong>and</strong> for all farmers together. Specification <strong>of</strong> the equation is as follows<br />

RC = f (Age, credit, Gender, Farm Size, Family Size, Non-farm income source <strong>and</strong> Farm<br />

Assets)<br />

Where,<br />

RC: Risk Coefficient<br />

Age: Age in number <strong>of</strong> years<br />

Credit: Access to formal credit agency (O=No Access, I = Access to Formal Agency)<br />

Gender: Sex <strong>of</strong> the household head (O=Female, I=Male)<br />

Farm Size: The size <strong>of</strong> the farm (in Hectare)<br />

Family Size: Number <strong>of</strong> household members<br />

Non-Farm Income source: Having non-farm income source (O=No, I=Yes)<br />

Farm Assets: Value <strong>of</strong> farm assets (in Rs.)<br />

The results are presented in table 6.8. Among the income related factors, farm size<br />

<strong>and</strong> access to non-farm income source played a significant role in explaining risk<br />

behaviour <strong>of</strong> the farmers. Farm size is negatively, <strong>and</strong> non-farm income source positively<br />

<strong>and</strong> significantly related with the risk coefficient. An inverse relation between risk<br />

coefficient <strong>and</strong> farm size signifies that farmers who attained a Safety-First position in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> their risk attitudes also have bigger farm size. Farmers with higher farm size can<br />

eam more income from the crop (due to higher level <strong>of</strong> production) <strong>and</strong> can have higher<br />

income from crop in relation to their disaster level <strong>of</strong> income. Access to non-farm income<br />

lis proved to be significant factor in explaining the risk attitude <strong>of</strong> fanners growing<br />

cauliflower. Farmers, whose disaster level <strong>of</strong> income is higher than the expected income<br />

174


from the crop, can afford to be risk takers as non-farm income source provided them<br />

safeguard, in terms <strong>of</strong> available money for meeting the minimum consumption needs <strong>of</strong><br />

the households. Family size is positively <strong>and</strong> significantly correlated with the risk<br />

attitude. As the family size increases, the disaster level <strong>of</strong> income is expected to increase<br />

as family members require more food for consumption which can influence the risk<br />

coefficient adverselyl. These high value crops are capital-intensive; huge expenditure is<br />

required for not only production <strong>of</strong> the crop, but also for its marketing 52 • The fanners,<br />

whose risk coefficient is positive, are able to allocate higher amount <strong>of</strong> area to these crops<br />

due to their access to credit.<br />

Tbl68Ft If}<br />

Roy's Risk<br />

a e . . ac ors n uencmg Ri k Attitud<br />

s eso f F armers<br />

Cauliflower Apple Growing<br />

Coefficient as a Growing Farmers Farmers<br />

Dependent Variable<br />

Constant -2.157 (-1.967) -0.502 (-0.384)<br />

Age 0.004 (0.327) -0.008 (-0.419)<br />

Credit 1.124 (3.011)* 0.150 (0.384)<br />

Gender 0.086 (0.207) 0.860 (1.856)<br />

Farm Size -0.173 (-3.128)* -0.027 (-0.571)<br />

Family size 0.160 (2.455)** 0.125 (1.170)<br />

Non-farm income 1.233 (3.492)* 1.117 (2.939)*<br />

Assets 3.11E-05 (1.128 -3.6E-05 (-1.545)<br />

All Farmers<br />

-0.706 (-0.856)<br />

-0.013 (-1.183)<br />

0.614 (2.269)**<br />

0.494 (1.613)<br />

-0.087 (-2.577)**<br />

0.175 (3.160)*<br />

1.075 (4.146)*<br />

-1.23 E-05 (-0.767)<br />

FIgures In the Parenthesis are t-values<br />

All Farmers: R': 0.277 Adjusted R':O.249, N~120<br />

Cauliflower R': 0.444 Adjusted R':0.369, N~O<br />

Apple R': 0.239, Adjusted R':0.136,N~<br />

• <strong>and</strong> •• signifies level <strong>of</strong> significance at I % <strong>and</strong> S % respectively<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

III Make risk coefficient positive<br />

" Capital is required for grading, packaging <strong>and</strong> transport purpose.<br />

175


6.5. Role <strong>of</strong> Economic Factors in L<strong>and</strong> Allocation in Favour <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong><br />

L<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> high value crops like horticultural crops is considered<br />

as one <strong>of</strong> the vital components <strong>of</strong> growth in agriculturaI sector. Such higher allocation<br />

can be influenced by both economic <strong>and</strong> socio-economic considerations at the fann level.<br />

Since higher allocation to these commercial crops tend to reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong><br />

available for the production <strong>of</strong> food crop, the disparity between food requirements at<br />

home <strong>and</strong> the actual food production may influence the extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation to<br />

commercial crops. In addition, since, horticultural crops are highly labour <strong>and</strong> capital<br />

intensive, labour availability at home <strong>and</strong> access to credit <strong>and</strong> non-fann income sources<br />

together influence such decisions. Among economic factors, variables relating to price<br />

<strong>and</strong> income from the crop are considered as factors that may influence l<strong>and</strong> allocation<br />

decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers.<br />

6.5.1. Typology <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Allocation<br />

The typology <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> horticulturaI crops is measured by the<br />

extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocated towards the selected crops. L<strong>and</strong> allocation towards these crops<br />

would be identical to the area under the selected crops in the total net cropped area. The<br />

results <strong>of</strong> the extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation towards apple <strong>and</strong> cauliflower in the villages show<br />

that these crops are <strong>of</strong> high significance for the farmers in terms <strong>of</strong> their livelihood; the<br />

crops cover over 50% <strong>of</strong> their net cropped area in the villages (table 6.9). The typology <strong>of</strong><br />

l<strong>and</strong> allocation across different farm sizes shows that in the case <strong>of</strong> cauliflower, large<br />

farmers scores over others in the extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation made towards the crop. Below<br />

them comes the category <strong>of</strong> marginal farmers (table 6.10). This illustrates that marginal<br />

farmers also have been able to allocate a considerable amount <strong>of</strong> area. Coming to apple<br />

crops, we find that small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers made the highest allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> in<br />

favour <strong>of</strong> the crop. It is important to mention that small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers together<br />

own less area than farmers <strong>of</strong> other groups; their decision <strong>of</strong> allocating more area to high<br />

I value crop can be either an accuml!lative or survival strategy (Chaplin, 2000). In several<br />

176


circumstances, small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers allocate large area to high value but risky<br />

crops in order to fight against poverty, which confirms the risk-taking capacity <strong>of</strong> the<br />

small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers. Hence, it is not right to view on high allocation towards high<br />

value crop as a high growth strategy; additional infonnation about the effect <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong><br />

allocation decisions on farmers' welfare in tenns <strong>of</strong> its effect on income <strong>and</strong> risk patterns<br />

<strong>of</strong> the farmers need to be collected to make the analysis meaningful.<br />

. . x en 0 an • F<br />

Table 6 9· E t t f L d All ocation ID avour 0 fD ortieu . I tu ral C roDS<br />

Variable<br />

Inlcator Cauliflower Apple<br />

ViIIa.oel Villal!. n Total Villan m V_.IV<br />

Proporti .... <strong>of</strong> (all:A)<br />

Selected crop area<br />

10 Net Cropped<br />

Ar .. 49.95 54.21 46.47 70.05 67.18<br />

Note.<br />

i. (a;I1:A)= proportion <strong>of</strong> area (a) under particular crop (i) in the Net Cropped Area (A)<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

. .<br />

To ... 1<br />

.:<br />

68.85 5425<br />

Table 6 10· Extent <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Allocation in Favour <strong>of</strong> <strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> by Farm Size<br />

Farm Size Share <strong>of</strong> area under apple or cauliflower to GCA<br />

CauIillower<br />

Marginal 58.33<br />

Small 52.67<br />

Semi-medium 51.78<br />

Medium 35.20<br />

Large 62.61<br />

Apple<br />

Marginal 71.62<br />

Small 72.98<br />

Semi-medium 69.06<br />

Medium 51.86<br />

Large: 66.90<br />

Source. Primary Data<br />

6.5.2. Socio-Economic Characteristics <strong>and</strong> L<strong>and</strong> AUocation<br />

ale<br />

Socio-economic factors can exert significant influence on the extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong><br />

allocation towards horticultural crops through their affect on resource availability <strong>and</strong><br />

risk management abilities <strong>of</strong> farmers. The results indicate that family size <strong>and</strong> number <strong>of</strong><br />

dependents tend to decrease the level <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> apple <strong>and</strong> cauliflower<br />

increases (table 6.11). This shows that more dependants <strong>and</strong> higher food requirements at<br />

~ome act as a constraint to increasing allocation. to high value commercial. crops. The<br />

l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops IS higher among the fanners WIth low farm<br />

177


size. In tenns <strong>of</strong> irrigation, which is important for the cauliflower crop for its production<br />

<strong>and</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>itability, there is a positive relation between level <strong>of</strong> allocation <strong>and</strong> irrigation<br />

intensity. As the l<strong>and</strong> allocation to cauliflower increases, the net irrigated area also<br />

increases. But, the same is not the case with apple, which does not require irrigation for<br />

production purpose. Higher ratio <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> to labour indicates the availability <strong>of</strong> home<br />

labour, which in tum influences the decision <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation towards horticultural crop.<br />

In both the cases <strong>of</strong> apple <strong>and</strong> cauliflower, there is a negative relation between the level<br />

<strong>of</strong>l<strong>and</strong> allocation to high value crop <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> to labour ratio. This indicates that more the<br />

quantum <strong>of</strong> home labour, for which the farmers are not supposed to incur any additional<br />

cost, more the l<strong>and</strong> allocation to high value crops. Reluctance to hire more labour <strong>and</strong><br />

disinclination to bear more input costs results in lower level <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation towards<br />

high value crops.<br />

Table 6 . 11· . Socio-Economic Characteristics at Different Levels <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Allocation<br />

I, Share <strong>of</strong> ,elected crop .... Family Number <strong>of</strong> Farm Irrigation LaDdlLabour Ann~<br />

toGCA size dependants size inttDsity*<br />

,<br />

N.On-far".<br />

i<br />

(No.) (No.) (ha)<br />

IlICOlne<br />

(~.)<br />

Cauliflower Low «0.33) 7.83 2.92 4.56 55.07 0.44 IOI95s-<br />

Medium 6.17 2.03 2.72 63.60 0.33 87331'--<br />

(0.33-0.66)<br />

Higb (>0.. 66) 6.92 2.50 1.93 88.13 0.23 50419--<br />

: Apple Low «0.33) 7.57 2.86 6.05 14.92 0.77 18 1403-<br />

Medium 7.33 2.25 4.23 18.55 0.50 171584--<br />

(0.33-0.66)<br />

High (>0.66) 5.78 1.51 4.67 7.80 0.69 93958-<br />

* Percenta g e <strong>of</strong> Net Irri ga ted Area to Net C rapped Area<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

Information on the farmer family's per capita food expenditure <strong>and</strong> income, their<br />

level <strong>of</strong> dependency on market for food <strong>and</strong> total income including farm <strong>and</strong> non-farm<br />

were obtained (table 6.12). This information would help us in finding the relevance <strong>of</strong> the<br />

socio-economic factors pertaining to food security <strong>of</strong> farmers to their l<strong>and</strong> allocation<br />

decisions. It is possible that higher farm income <strong>of</strong> the farmers tends to improve the<br />

overall consumption <strong>of</strong> the farmers. Such farmers would be less concerned about the<br />

production <strong>of</strong> food crops. For a comparison, food-security indicators pertaining to other<br />

measures <strong>of</strong> diversification including index <strong>of</strong> concentration <strong>and</strong> number <strong>of</strong> crops<br />

lproduced in a year are also presented.<br />

~<br />

178


Table 6 12' In<br />

. . come-c onsumption G ap at Different Levels <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Allocation<br />

Extent <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

Total annuli food Totll aanual Total gap between Pertentage <strong>of</strong> food<br />

expenditure (in income - farm per capita iDcome crop obtained from..<br />

per capita) (RI.) <strong>and</strong> non-farm. (in. <strong>and</strong> per capita l<strong>and</strong> to total food<br />

' Der caDit. Hils.) cODSIlIDDtion oi •. ) tonsumtd (%)<br />

Share <strong>of</strong> divenified trop area to GCA<br />

Cauliflower Low 10644 23661 13017<br />

Growers<br />

Medium 10610 23451 12841<br />

Hiltb 9853 17117 7264<br />

Apple Low 10076 42472 32396<br />

Growers<br />

Medium 9700 42316 32615<br />

High 10640 57001 46360<br />

Index <strong>of</strong> Concentration merfmdabllndu)<br />

Cauliflower Low 9999 16689 7645<br />

Growers Medium 10274 23435 14332<br />

Hil1.b 11283 26077 16108<br />

Apple Low 10756 67781 57337<br />

Growers Medium 10436 50625 40608<br />

Hil(b 9655 30751 22398<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> crops produces in a Yelr<br />

Cauliflower Low 10016 16987 7900<br />

Growers Medium 9944 18425 9647<br />

High 11099 28138 18322<br />

Apple Low 10587 77892 67503<br />

Growers Medium 10176 41913 32137<br />

Hil(b 10651 40068 30891<br />

Note.<br />

i. For the distribution <strong>of</strong> share <strong>of</strong> diversified crop area to GCA <strong>and</strong> Index <strong>of</strong> concentration, low, medium<br />

<strong>and</strong> high signifies below 0.33, between 0.33 <strong>and</strong> 0.66 <strong>and</strong> above 0.66 <strong>of</strong> the values respectively. The range<br />

<strong>of</strong> both the distribution is from 0 to I.<br />

ii. For the distribution <strong>of</strong> number <strong>of</strong> crops, low, medium <strong>and</strong> high signifies crops produced below, around<br />

<strong>and</strong> above the average number <strong>of</strong> crops produced in a year. For cauliflower <strong>and</strong> apple average number <strong>of</strong><br />

crops produced in a year is 4.20 <strong>and</strong> 3.33 croPs respectively.<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

The results illustrate that for cauliflower as the level <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocated to high value<br />

crop increases, the per capita expenditure on food decreases. But, this is accompanied by<br />

a fall in per capita income as l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> horticultural crop increases.<br />

However, at the higher level <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation to high value crop, the gap between the<br />

per capita income <strong>and</strong> expenditure is lowest; this confirms that the farmers who have<br />

allocated more l<strong>and</strong> to high value crop face higher risk <strong>of</strong> food security. On the contrary,<br />

though the per capital food expenditure declines with increased level <strong>of</strong> allocation for<br />

apple plantation, the gap between the income <strong>and</strong> food expenditure widens with every<br />

increase in the l<strong>and</strong> allocation level. This means that farmers who have allocated more<br />

l<strong>and</strong> to high value crop are at lower risk <strong>of</strong> food insecurity.<br />

I<br />

16.48<br />

9.16<br />

9.78<br />

8.14<br />

10.67<br />

3.95<br />

8.04<br />

11.20<br />

11.91<br />

2.04<br />

4.66<br />

14.57<br />

8.40<br />

11.l6<br />

12.00<br />

1.50<br />

4.67<br />

16.48<br />

179


A contrasting picture is seen when other indices <strong>of</strong> diversification such as aggregate<br />

level <strong>of</strong> spread in the cropping pattern <strong>and</strong> number <strong>of</strong> crops produced in a year are taken<br />

into account. As both the spread <strong>and</strong> diversity increases, in general, the aggregate food<br />

expenditure increases. However, an increase in income is noticed only for cauliflower<br />

growers <strong>and</strong> not for apple growers. This shows that increasing the number <strong>of</strong> crops by<br />

cauliflower growers has a favourable effect on reducing food security problems, whereas<br />

it is not necessarily true for apple growers. However, overall, the gap between the income<br />

<strong>and</strong> consumption is far higher for apple growers as compared to cauliflower growers due<br />

to difference in the pr<strong>of</strong>itability ratios <strong>of</strong> these crops. Hence, apple growers are more food<br />

secure in comparison to cauliflower growers.<br />

6.5.3. L<strong>and</strong> Allocation at Different Levels <strong>of</strong> Expectations <strong>and</strong><br />

Risk Attitudes<br />

Examining the role <strong>of</strong> risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty in the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions by<br />

farmers, a grouping is made <strong>of</strong> the farmers on the basis <strong>of</strong> the different levels <strong>of</strong> their<br />

expectations (price, yield <strong>and</strong> income) <strong>and</strong> risk attitude (Safety-First <strong>and</strong> risk-takers).<br />

The extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> the selected horticultural crops is computed<br />

across different levels <strong>of</strong> expectations <strong>and</strong> risk attitude. Again, the results are presented<br />

separately for cauliflower <strong>and</strong> apple (table 6.13).<br />

Price expectation is higher among farmers with larger holdings. Since, higher<br />

expectation <strong>of</strong> price is generally influenced by the level <strong>of</strong> maximum price received by<br />

the farmer, it can be assumed that farmers with large farm size have a better advantage in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> their bargaining power in the market <strong>and</strong> they tend to realize higher price for<br />

their produce. The results also suggest that as the expectation about price increases, the<br />

level <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> horticultural crop decreases. When the expected<br />

production per ha <strong>of</strong> the farms is taken alone, there emerges a contrast between its<br />

relationship with farm size <strong>and</strong> extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> both the crops. In<br />

the case <strong>of</strong> apple, the expectation <strong>of</strong> production per ha increases with the increase in farm<br />

I size, <strong>and</strong> extent <strong>of</strong>l<strong>and</strong> allocation increases as the production per ha improves. However,<br />

180


the same is not true <strong>of</strong> cauliflower where, farmers with expectation <strong>of</strong> higher production<br />

per ha are found to have lower fann size <strong>and</strong> relatively lower extent <strong>of</strong>l<strong>and</strong> allocation. As<br />

far as the expected income from the crop is concerned, it was bigher for larger farms for<br />

both crops. There is a direct <strong>and</strong> positive relationship between the total income<br />

expectation <strong>and</strong> level <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation to horticultura1 crops. The farmers, who have<br />

bigher income expectation from the crop, allocated higher extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation to<br />

cauliflower <strong>and</strong> apple crops. This confIrms that the income expectation does play an<br />

important role in l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions <strong>of</strong> the farmers.<br />

Table 6.13: Role <strong>of</strong> Expectations <strong>and</strong> Risk 00 Extent <strong>of</strong> Laod Allocation in Favour <strong>of</strong><br />

H omcu • I tura I <strong>Crops</strong><br />

Cauliflower<br />

Apple<br />

Farm Extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> Farm Extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong><br />

Size (ha) Allocation (a,lL\) Size (ba) Allocation<br />

(.~A)<br />

Price E!pectation<br />

Low Expectation 2.90 53.20 5.06 91.23<br />

Medium Expectation 2.79 50.70 3.72 91.87<br />

High Expectation 3.28 52.62 5.10 89.23<br />

Yield Expectation (productioDlba)<br />

Low Expectation 3.27 58.71 3.20 87.45<br />

Medium Expectation 3.22 50.09 5.38 90.01<br />

High Expectation 2.04 45.81 6.22 97.71<br />

Income Expectation (IWba)<br />

Low Expectation 2.08 46.48 3.05 88.54<br />

Medium Expectation 3.27 50.64 3.44 88.31<br />

High E~ctation 3.00 57.69 5.89 92.66<br />

Risk Coefficient<br />

Safety·First 3.27 60.75 5.64 95.60<br />

Risk-takers 2.63 44.29 3.84 86.05<br />

Note.<br />

\. In the case <strong>of</strong> expectation <strong>of</strong> yield, for cauliflower, the fanners with low, medium <strong>and</strong> high expectations are 21,<br />

23 <strong>and</strong> 16 respectively <strong>and</strong> for apple it is 23, 23, <strong>and</strong> 14 respectively. In the case <strong>of</strong> expectations <strong>of</strong> total income<br />

for cauliflower, the farmers with low, medium <strong>and</strong> high expectations are 13,28 <strong>and</strong> 19 respectively <strong>and</strong> for apple<br />

it is 14, 12 <strong>and</strong> 34 respectively. In Ihe case <strong>of</strong> risk coefficient, for cauliflower, Ihe fanners with Safety-First <strong>and</strong><br />

risk-takers are 28 <strong>and</strong> 32 respectively <strong>and</strong> for apple it is 30 <strong>and</strong> 30 respectively<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

Coming to risk attitudes, it is the small farms that take more risk in their production<br />

decisions. In regard to apple <strong>and</strong> cauliflower, Safety-First farmers have higher farm size,<br />

whereas farmers with risk-taking behaviour have relatively low farm size. However, the<br />

extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> horticultural crop by risk-taking faJTIlers is lower<br />

Ithan Safety-First farmers. Due to higher income <strong>and</strong> lower food consumption<br />

requirements as also low variance, fanners who allocated higher amount <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> in favour<br />

181


<strong>of</strong>horticulturaJ crops are found to have performed better in terms <strong>of</strong> Safety-Fin;t position.<br />

It confirms that the overall risk <strong>of</strong> consumption <strong>and</strong> production did playa significant role<br />

in explaining the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions <strong>of</strong> fannen;. Higher risk <strong>of</strong> conswnption <strong>and</strong><br />

production jointly influence the extent <strong>of</strong>l<strong>and</strong> allocation.<br />

6.5.4. Determinants <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Allocation in Favour <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>Horticultural</strong> <strong>Crops</strong><br />

In order to capture the role <strong>of</strong> risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty in the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions by<br />

fannen;, variables which have a direct bearing on fannen;' expectations about price <strong>and</strong><br />

income 53 were identified along with their focused revenue from the crop, variation <strong>of</strong><br />

crop revenue <strong>and</strong> fannen;' disaster level <strong>of</strong> income levels. Expectations about the price <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> income 54 from the crop influence the prospective outcome that fanners expect from<br />

the extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation to a given crop. In general, fannen; who expect high price<br />

<strong>and</strong> income from the crop are likely to have higher allocation <strong>of</strong> area in favour <strong>of</strong> the<br />

given crop. The variable- focused income which is the mean value <strong>of</strong> the focused gain<br />

<strong>and</strong> focused loss by the farmer 55 is also included. Higher variability <strong>of</strong> returns from the<br />

crop is expected to adversely affect the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decision. It is important to note<br />

that while making the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decision, the fanner takes different types <strong>of</strong> risks<br />

that include not only the risk <strong>of</strong> production but also that <strong>of</strong> consumption among others.<br />

Farmer enters into a trade-<strong>of</strong>f situation while taking decisions on allocating area to<br />

commercial crops. Higher food consumption requirements vis a vis the total food<br />

production capacity <strong>of</strong> the l<strong>and</strong> tend to influence the extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation to the<br />

commercial crop. In other words, greater the food requirement at home, lesser will be the<br />

extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation to horticultural crop by the farmer. It is not only food crop<br />

" To deal with risk <strong>and</strong> to hedge losses effectively with l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions requires underst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

the individual farms expected future variability <strong>of</strong> income by potential crop (Sumner, 2004)<br />

54 The expected Income is obtained by multiplying the expected price <strong>and</strong> expected yield <strong>of</strong>the crop.<br />

jS Favourable <strong>and</strong> unfavourable outcomes results from most actions including l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions.<br />

The degree <strong>of</strong> concern for a particular outcome probably increases as the likelihood <strong>of</strong> its occurrences<br />

\ decreases. Those extreme outcomes, which are sli.1I thought <strong>of</strong> as possible <strong>and</strong> which are <strong>of</strong> most interests<br />

to the decision maker are termed as the focus gam <strong>and</strong> focus loss by the farmer (Webster <strong>and</strong> Kennedy.<br />

1975)<br />

182


equirements or expenditures that are <strong>of</strong> vital importance to fanners, but also other home<br />

expenditures like children' ~ education expenses etc. which are even more important.<br />

Therefore, here the disaster level <strong>of</strong> income is used as a variable, which includes all<br />

critical expenditures <strong>and</strong> food requirements at home. Disaster level <strong>of</strong> income is expected<br />

to effectively higher allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> to high value commercial crops. The specification<br />

<strong>of</strong> the equation is as follows<br />

alIA = f(EP, EY, FY, N <strong>and</strong> DL Y)56<br />

Where,<br />

alIA is the proportion <strong>of</strong> area under the crop aj (cauliflower or apple) to the total net<br />

cropped area (LA)<br />

EP: Expected price is the price that fanners expects from the crop<br />

EY: Expected Income is the income that farmers expects from the crop<br />

FY: Focused Income is the mean value <strong>of</strong> the focused loss <strong>and</strong> gain by the farmer<br />

N: Income variability is measured by the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation <strong>of</strong> output by using 3 years<br />

fannleveldata<strong>and</strong><br />

DL Y: Disaster level <strong>of</strong> income is the minimum income requirement at home<br />

The results indicate that income expectation <strong>and</strong> not the price expectation<br />

influences farmers' decision <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation to the horticultural crops (table 6.14). The<br />

income expectation variable is positive <strong>and</strong> significant for fanners growing cauliflower<br />

crop but, for apple growers it is only positive but not statistically significant. Expected<br />

price variable is negative <strong>and</strong> insignificant for apple growers. Interestingly, for apple<br />

growers, the focused income from the crop, which is the mean value <strong>of</strong> the focused gain<br />

<strong>and</strong> loss from the crop, comes out positive <strong>and</strong> statistically significant. This is because<br />

apple crop has a gestation period <strong>of</strong> production <strong>and</strong> as l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> apple<br />

is mostly inflexible in terms <strong>of</strong> reallocation to crops. Higher variation in the revenue from<br />

crop is negative <strong>and</strong> significant for cauliflower crop. This explains how higher risk<br />

adversely affected their l<strong>and</strong> allocation decision. The disaster level <strong>of</strong> income has a<br />

16 .<br />

I The log values are used for regressIOn purposes<br />

183


negative influence on l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> apple <strong>and</strong> cauliflower crops as the<br />

coefficien.t is negative <strong>and</strong> statistically significant. This shows that higher food<br />

consumption requirements <strong>and</strong> other critical expenditures do influence the behaviour <strong>of</strong><br />

farmers in their decision in regard to allocating l<strong>and</strong> to high value commercial crop.<br />

Table 6.14: Factors Affecting L<strong>and</strong> Allocation Decisions <strong>of</strong> Farmers Producing<br />

Hrti 0 cn I tura Ie rops<br />

L<strong>and</strong> allocation as a<br />

In Favour <strong>of</strong> cauliflower<br />

Dependant Variable<br />

Coefficient<br />

Constant 6.\30 (4.336)<br />

Expected Price 0.089 (0.386)-<br />

Expected Yield 0.142** (2.1521<br />

Focused Income 0.076 (1.285)<br />

Income Variability -0.167** (2.207)<br />

Disaster level <strong>of</strong> Income ·0.280* (3.210\<br />

Note.<br />

i. Figures in the Parenthesis are t-values<br />

ii. Cauliflower R2: 0.491 Adjusted R2 :0.444, N9;O<br />

Apple R2: 0.366 Adjusted R2: 0.307.N~60<br />

iii. * <strong>and</strong> ** signifies level <strong>of</strong> significance at I % <strong>and</strong> 5 % respectively<br />

Source: Primary Data<br />

In Favour <strong>of</strong> apple<br />

Coeffic:ient<br />

6.953 (7.662)<br />

-0.218 (1.673)<br />

0.027 (0.921)<br />

0.103** (l27)<br />

-0.045 (1.593)<br />

-0.253 .. (3.543)<br />

6.6. Summary<br />

Higher allocation <strong>of</strong>l<strong>and</strong> in favour <strong>of</strong> high value crops like fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables is<br />

desirable from the point <strong>of</strong> view <strong>of</strong> not only raising the farm income <strong>and</strong> productivity <strong>of</strong><br />

the farmers but also to create high employment in this sector in India. Among economic<br />

factors, both price <strong>and</strong> income are the major incentives for the farmers to decide on the<br />

allocation <strong>of</strong> resources like elastic <strong>and</strong> inelastic factors <strong>of</strong> production, such as l<strong>and</strong>. Here,<br />

the major aim was to examine the relevance <strong>of</strong> uncertainty <strong>and</strong> risk on the l<strong>and</strong> allocation<br />

decisions by farmers which acts as a proxy for diversification towards horticultural crops.<br />

Information about the farmers' expectations are elicited <strong>and</strong> their risk attitudes measured;<br />

they are then linked with the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions.<br />

There is a huge difference in the price expectations among the horticultural<br />

producers which is influenced by the price received by them. Improvement in market<br />

. infrastructure that results in better price realization is likely to influence the price<br />

lexpectations. Better expectation <strong>of</strong> prices results in use <strong>of</strong> more inputs by the farmers <strong>and</strong><br />

184


higher price expectations improve the input-use propensity <strong>of</strong> farmers in terms <strong>of</strong> higher<br />

intensity <strong>of</strong> labour, more willingness to pay for hired labour <strong>and</strong> more willingness to<br />

reinvest pr<strong>of</strong>its in l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> crop related activities. But, for the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decision,<br />

price expectation alone cannot explain the behaviour <strong>of</strong> the farmer. It is the output per ha<br />

that is more important in explaining their decision. In other words, income expectations<br />

by the farmers are critical in improving the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions. Farmers, generally,<br />

take into account the aggregate gain from the crop in their decision rather than referring<br />

to the expected price <strong>of</strong> the crop. Their capacity to generate higher productivity along<br />

with the better market prospects together explains farmers' decision regarding allocating<br />

l<strong>and</strong> to high value crops. It is important to build a market structure in order to influence<br />

input-use propensities <strong>of</strong> farmers, but is not sufficient condition for improving farmers'<br />

readiness to increase the inelastic factor <strong>of</strong> production i.e., l<strong>and</strong> in favour <strong>of</strong> high value<br />

crops.<br />

By application <strong>of</strong> the risk coefficient measure, it is found that most <strong>of</strong> the<br />

cauliflower growing farmers are risk-takers than risk averse. Over 61 percent farmers<br />

growing cauliflower have a positive risk coefficient evidencing their risk-taking nature in<br />

l<strong>and</strong> allocation decision. In contrast to the cauliflower growers, most apple growers take a<br />

safety-first position while taking the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decision. The difference between<br />

apple <strong>and</strong> cauliflower growers can be attributed mainly to the difference in the income<br />

potential <strong>of</strong> the crop concerned; income potential is relatively higher for apple growing<br />

farmers. In addition, most apple growers have large farm size as compared to cauliflower<br />

growers, which again contributes to the difference in income between the two groups.<br />

The farm size <strong>and</strong> access to non-farm income source are found to have played a<br />

significant role in the risk behaviour <strong>of</strong> farmers. Farmers whose disaster level <strong>of</strong> income<br />

is higher than the expected income from the crop can afford to be risk takers as non-farm<br />

income source would hedge their secure position. Family size is positive <strong>and</strong> significantly<br />

correlated with the risk attitude. As the family size increases, the disaster level <strong>of</strong> income<br />

is also expected to be high as family member require more food for consumption <strong>and</strong><br />

higher outlays for expenditures. This can influence the risk coefficient adversely.<br />

185


Availability <strong>of</strong> credit is positively related with the risk coefficient, indicating that risktakers<br />

could do so by having access to credit.<br />

186


AJlPendix 6.1: Farmers Experience with Price <strong>of</strong> Cauliflower (R.lI


CHAPTER VII<br />

CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS<br />

Agricultural is still the vital sector <strong>of</strong> Indian economy as it contributes around one<br />

fourth to the GDP <strong>and</strong> employs more than 58 percent <strong>of</strong> its population. Growth <strong>of</strong><br />

agricultura1 sector is contingent upon several instruments that include quality <strong>and</strong><br />

quantity <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong>, technological progress, market development <strong>and</strong> crop diversification.<br />

The slow down in agricultural growth after mid 1990s was attributed to increased pattern<br />

<strong>of</strong> specialisation, higher orientation towards a few food grains, incomplete agricultura1<br />

transformation <strong>and</strong> fatigue in major components <strong>of</strong> growth. These reflected in the growth<br />

rates <strong>of</strong> area <strong>and</strong> productivity. Recently, diversification has assumed high importance in<br />

the policy pertaining to growth <strong>of</strong> the sector. Policy makers have been tracking the<br />

factors provoking diversification towards high value crops in the face <strong>of</strong> stagnant yields<br />

<strong>of</strong> food-grains. The impact <strong>of</strong> crop specialisation on environment has dampened the<br />

agricultural growth, <strong>and</strong> slow down in other instruments <strong>of</strong> growth. Interestingly, this<br />

slow down forced a change <strong>and</strong> the shift is also necessitated by the opening up <strong>of</strong> the<br />

market to the world. Sustained economic growth, rising per capita income <strong>and</strong> growing<br />

urbanization have been causing a shift in the consumption patterns in favour <strong>of</strong> highvalue<br />

food commodities like fiuits, vegetables, dairy, poultry, meat <strong>and</strong> fish products<br />

from staple food such as rice, wheat <strong>and</strong> coarse cereals. All these situations made crop<br />

diversification as an important buzz word in the agricultural sector in India.<br />

Crop diversification is one <strong>of</strong> the sub-sets <strong>of</strong> a larger matrix <strong>of</strong> production<br />

alternatives in the cropping sector that has several sub-components. These components<br />

include first the diversity in the cropping pattern or spread <strong>of</strong> crops, <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation to<br />

high value crops. It also includes change in the cropping pattern among different crops.<br />

These components together <strong>and</strong> not in isolation affect the economy <strong>of</strong> the farmer in terms<br />

<strong>of</strong> income <strong>and</strong> risk outcomes. It can be argued that a mere increase in the total number <strong>of</strong><br />

crops or more diversity in the cropping pattern may not promise more income or less risk.<br />

But, it is also specificities <strong>of</strong> diversification that decide on the income <strong>and</strong> risk effect. At<br />

188


the same time, impact <strong>of</strong> other components <strong>of</strong> diversification on growth <strong>of</strong> output is<br />

dependent on several factors. The differences in dimensions <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>and</strong> its<br />

varying relationship with growth raise some important questions: Why do farmers need<br />

diversification, <strong>and</strong> under what context? What provokes diversification? Secondly, as<br />

there could be either growth inducing or depressing effects <strong>of</strong> diversification, under<br />

which circumstances diversification assume more importance? Which is better process <strong>of</strong><br />

diversification take place, <strong>and</strong> in which direction it must move i.e. at the crop <strong>and</strong><br />

regional level? What are the areas <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>and</strong> finally, diversification at what<br />

level?<br />

High Value <strong>Crops</strong> as a <strong>Case</strong> for <strong>Diversification</strong> in India<br />

In India, after independence, both market <strong>and</strong> technology were under developed <strong>and</strong><br />

these were responsible for low income <strong>and</strong> higher variability in the returns to food <strong>and</strong><br />

non-food crops. It was then diversification was viewed primarily from the angle <strong>of</strong> risk<br />

<strong>and</strong> food security. <strong>Diversification</strong>, in terms <strong>of</strong> diversity <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern, was thought<br />

<strong>of</strong> as one <strong>of</strong> the means to minimize risk <strong>and</strong> overcome food insecurity. The introduction<br />

<strong>of</strong> Green Revolution was one <strong>of</strong> the steps towards changing the orientation <strong>of</strong> farmers in<br />

India towards adoption <strong>of</strong> new <strong>and</strong> better technology. The Technology Mission on<br />

Oilseeds (TMO) in late 1980s was an additional effort to improve the technology in<br />

another crucial sector <strong>of</strong> agriculture in India. A mechanism <strong>of</strong> price support <strong>and</strong> subsidies<br />

was operationalized to improve such technology-led diversification. This led to reduction<br />

in the level <strong>of</strong> diversity among crops <strong>and</strong> increased concentration <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern as<br />

large area was diverted towards a few prominent crops i.e., rice <strong>and</strong> wheat. Such<br />

development initiative or policy came under critical lens, particularly after the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> World Trade Organization (WTO) in 1995. Higher economic growth <strong>and</strong><br />

increased per capita income during 1990s, favoured the process <strong>of</strong> price-led<br />

diversification as it was based on shifting <strong>of</strong> area towards crops whose dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

consequently price were increasing at a faster rate.<br />

There are many additional justifications for emphasizing on diversification towards<br />

~igh value crops in India. On the b~is <strong>of</strong> supply side conditions, the major factor that<br />

189


aises the need for diversification is the poor perfonnance <strong>of</strong> agricultural sector in the<br />

recent past. Policy initiatives in the past were blamed for present picture <strong>of</strong> gloom in<br />

agricultural sector (Hazra, 2003, <strong>and</strong> Rudra, 1982). The emphasis on cereal production<br />

over the last three decades in India has resulted in low output prices <strong>and</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>itability for<br />

cereals which led to dampened agricultural growth (Barghouti et aI. 2004). As significant<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> area was shifted towards high value food-grain crops including rice, wheat <strong>and</strong><br />

maize, it led to emerging scenario <strong>of</strong> specialisation in many states. The increased<br />

specialisation patterns resulted in the emergence <strong>of</strong> environmental concerns <strong>and</strong><br />

sustainability issues that expounds on the need for diversification towards other high<br />

value crops. Additionally, as rising population pressure has been squeezing agricultural<br />

l<strong>and</strong> for cultivation (Joshi et aI., 2006) <strong>and</strong> several states in India are now hitting the<br />

upper limit in use <strong>of</strong> fertilizers <strong>and</strong> irrigation; therefore there is need to look for<br />

diversification towards high value crops as a policy option (Ch<strong>and</strong>, 2005).<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> in favour <strong>of</strong> high value crops is also advised on account <strong>of</strong> several<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>-side factors. The present stage <strong>of</strong> poor perfonnance in agriculture along with<br />

structural changes taking place_ in the economy provided a new opportunity for<br />

diversification. The consumption patterns in India has been shifting towards high-value<br />

commodities like fiuits, vegetables, dairy, poultry, meat <strong>and</strong> fish products from staple<br />

food such as rice, wheat <strong>and</strong> coarse cereals. This is evident from the share <strong>of</strong> these<br />

commodities in the total expenditure on food which increased from 34 percent in 1983 to<br />

44 percent in 1999-2000 in the rural areas, <strong>and</strong> from 55 to 63 percent in the urban areas<br />

(Kumar <strong>and</strong> Mmthyunjaya, 2002). In addition, trade liberalization <strong>and</strong> overall higher<br />

growth in the economy has resulted in high returns from many non-food-grain crops due<br />

to changes in the trade scenario <strong>and</strong> changing consumption pattern. On such a backdrop,<br />

the diversification <strong>of</strong> agriculture towards high value crops like fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables is<br />

suggested as a viable solution to stabilize <strong>and</strong> raise fann income, enhance agricultural<br />

growth, increase employment opportunities <strong>and</strong> conserve natural resources (Vyas, 1996<br />

<strong>and</strong> Joshi, 2005).<br />

190


Move towards Horticulture<br />

<strong>Horticultural</strong> crops emerged as a significant case representing diversification due to<br />

several reasons. The value <strong>and</strong> productivity <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops is far higher than any<br />

other crops. Available evidence shows that one hectare under horticultural crops (such as<br />

fruits) can generate an annual income <strong>of</strong> up to Rs. 20,000, in contrast to hardly Rs. 10,000<br />

<strong>and</strong> Rs. 4,000 by rice <strong>and</strong> ragi respectively (Singh et a1., 2004). Cultivation <strong>of</strong> fruits can<br />

also generate employment to the tune <strong>of</strong> 860 man-days as against 143 man-days by<br />

cereals In India, dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops <strong>and</strong> their exports have been continuously<br />

increasing <strong>and</strong> it is expected to increase faster in the near future. The consumption <strong>of</strong><br />

fresh fruits was estimated at 25 kg per capita in 1981 <strong>and</strong> in 2001 approximated to 40 kg<br />

per capita, an increase <strong>of</strong> 60010 in the last two decades. The annual per capita consumption<br />

<strong>of</strong> vegetables increased from 47 kg in 1983 to 76 kg in 1999. The overall increase in<br />

vegetable consumption was about 53% during this period. Given the population base <strong>and</strong><br />

the fact that real per capita income levels increased at the rate <strong>of</strong> 3.4% per year between<br />

1981 <strong>and</strong> 1999, the household expenditure on F&V increased at 5% per annum during the<br />

period. It is understood that the relative significance <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops becoming<br />

highly remunerative due to price. There is a need to enhance area under these crops as<br />

there is a positive relation between an increase in the relevance <strong>of</strong> such crops <strong>and</strong> growth<br />

in overall crop output (Joshi et a1., 2006).<br />

Research Issues <strong>and</strong> Gaps<br />

Studies dealing with diversification cover a wide range <strong>of</strong> aspects <strong>and</strong> at the same<br />

time there are plethora <strong>of</strong> ways to interpret the significance <strong>of</strong> changing diversification.<br />

While dealing at macro level, the major debate is about the quantification <strong>and</strong><br />

significance <strong>of</strong> crop diversification in the growth <strong>of</strong> output. As noted, there are several<br />

sui>-components <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>and</strong> each component affects growth in a different way.<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> diversification towards high value crops, many researchers argue that a silent<br />

revolution <strong>of</strong> shift in cropping pattern towards high value crops is already under way<br />

(Joshi, 2006, Vyas, 1996, Ch<strong>and</strong>, 2005, Rao et aI, 2004, Birthal et al,. 2007). But, how<br />

the process <strong>of</strong> diversification has affected the growth <strong>of</strong> output in India. While dealing<br />

191


with this issue, many studies have dealt with the static aspects <strong>of</strong> diversification, without<br />

emphasising the dynamic aspect. Actually, diversification affec~ growth both through<br />

static <strong>and</strong> dynamic effects; a positive static effect <strong>of</strong> diversification would show a shift <strong>of</strong><br />

crop pattern in favour <strong>of</strong> high initial productivity crop. This does not, however, capture<br />

developments in the technology <strong>of</strong> crops that changes over time <strong>and</strong> may alter relative<br />

values <strong>of</strong> crops. Hence, it is important to consider the dynamic effects <strong>of</strong> diversification<br />

that capture the concomitant movements <strong>of</strong> yield <strong>and</strong> cropping pattern change.<br />

Any decision-making in the process <strong>of</strong> diversification towards high value crops<br />

could be analysed at both macro (state or district) <strong>and</strong> micro (farm) levels. At the macro<br />

level, such decisions are examined on the basis <strong>of</strong> price response models. However, there<br />

are several limitations to analysing the changing l<strong>and</strong> allocation decision using macro<br />

level data. Measurement <strong>of</strong> supply response usually requires time series data for<br />

quantities, cost <strong>and</strong> prices. Such data are not easily available least to think <strong>of</strong> reliability.<br />

There is a partial coverage in terms <strong>of</strong> crops <strong>and</strong> area. As a result, a large number <strong>of</strong> crops<br />

especially high value horticulturaI crops are found excluded from the analysis due to lack<br />

<strong>of</strong> reliable time series data on these crops in India. Another limitation <strong>of</strong> these models is<br />

regarding identification <strong>of</strong> the competing crops. Additionally, the macro level studies<br />

mainly concentrate on crop price as the major economic factor shaping farmers' changing<br />

l<strong>and</strong> allocation decision <strong>and</strong> seem to ignore income aspect. It could be hypothesized that<br />

farmers with relatively higher level <strong>of</strong> productivity allocate more l<strong>and</strong> to the crop with<br />

lower price expectation. Hence, we have examined the link between price <strong>and</strong> income<br />

with the shift in the cropping pattem decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers.<br />

Fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables are highly remunerative crops but these are also considered<br />

risky crops. The major feature <strong>of</strong> the horticultural crops is that the prices <strong>of</strong> the crops<br />

fluctuate widely even within a single season. Lack <strong>of</strong> any support price coupled with high<br />

perishability <strong>of</strong> these crops makes the horticultural growers even more vulnerable to risk<br />

<strong>and</strong> uncertainty than growers <strong>of</strong> other high value crops like rice or sugarcane. In the event<br />

<strong>of</strong> greater extent <strong>of</strong> risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty, the importance <strong>of</strong> the same is high for the<br />

farmers while taking l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions. At the farm level, the concept <strong>of</strong><br />

expectation is generally used in tenns <strong>of</strong> a response to uncertainty involved in the<br />

192


production process. Farmer tends to have expectations about different economic<br />

outcomes including price, yield <strong>and</strong> income. Therefore, we examined the link between<br />

different expectations including price, yield <strong>and</strong> income in the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions<br />

by fanners.<br />

Risk could also be generally considered a strong behavioural force impacting<br />

decision on l<strong>and</strong> allocation between food <strong>and</strong> commercial crop. A vital perspective <strong>of</strong> risk<br />

is how far <strong>and</strong> how <strong>of</strong>ten returns unable to reach a below mean level <strong>of</strong> return. In this<br />

context, risk is considered as the cost <strong>of</strong> decision in farmers' decision pertaining to l<strong>and</strong><br />

allocation to high value crops (Roumasset, 1976). The Safety-First principle (Roy, 1952)<br />

accounts for such costs in analyzing farmers' behaviour towards risk. Due to fluctuation<br />

in the components <strong>of</strong> revenue from the crop, one can find two kinds <strong>of</strong> fanners; the first<br />

group <strong>of</strong> farmers would prefer to be on safer side <strong>and</strong> hence their allocation decisions can<br />

be explained by the income <strong>and</strong> yield variance <strong>of</strong> their crop as relative to the perceived<br />

disaster level income <strong>of</strong> farm household. The second group constitutes farmers who<br />

prefer to take risk in their l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions. Here, farmers are risk-takers as their<br />

disaster level <strong>of</strong> income would be higher than the mean income from the crop produced<br />

for commercial purpose. The farmers take risk by increasing allocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> more in<br />

favour <strong>of</strong> high value crop against the subsistence crop <strong>and</strong> take the risk about their food<br />

consumption <strong>and</strong> the credibility <strong>of</strong> meeting other needs at home like education <strong>of</strong><br />

children, etc. But, not all farmers prefer to take such risk <strong>and</strong> hence keep their l<strong>and</strong><br />

allocation low in favour <strong>of</strong> commercial or high value crops. They follow the principle <strong>of</strong><br />

Safety-First as they tend to realize low utility from the production <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops.<br />

This <strong>of</strong>ten results in selection <strong>of</strong> low-risk crops that deters higher allocation to<br />

horticultural crops.<br />

In consideration <strong>of</strong> the gaps in available literature on the subject, we have chosen the<br />

following research questions; what is the nature <strong>and</strong> extent <strong>of</strong> crop diversification across<br />

states in India <strong>and</strong> its role in the growth <strong>of</strong> output in the agricultural sector? Whether the<br />

process <strong>of</strong> crop diversification in India has been growth inducive or depressive? What is<br />

the relative significance <strong>of</strong> economic <strong>and</strong> non-economic factors in diversi fication from<br />

food crops to horticultural crops? Whether it is the relative price or relative income that<br />

193


matters more in when farmers decides to diversify towards horticultural crops? What is<br />

the nature <strong>of</strong> price expectat!ons <strong>of</strong> farmers <strong>and</strong> its relationship with other economic<br />

factors such as crop yield, cost <strong>of</strong> production <strong>and</strong> input-use propensities? What is the<br />

relative importance <strong>of</strong> different expectations i.e. price, yield <strong>and</strong> income expectations <strong>of</strong><br />

the farmers on their l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions? Are the farmers growing horticultural<br />

crops averse to risk or not <strong>and</strong> what are the determinants <strong>of</strong> their risk behaviour? Does the<br />

higher risk <strong>of</strong> production <strong>and</strong> consumption hinder l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong><br />

horticultural crop by the farmers?<br />

Objectives <strong>of</strong> the Study<br />

The specific objectives <strong>of</strong> the study are<br />

(i) To investigate the relative role <strong>of</strong> diversification on output growth, <strong>and</strong> growth<br />

inducive or depressive impact <strong>of</strong> changing process <strong>of</strong> crop diversification in<br />

India,<br />

(ii) To analyse the nature <strong>of</strong> price expectations <strong>of</strong> the diversified farmers, examine<br />

its relationship with other economic factors <strong>and</strong> identify the role <strong>of</strong> different<br />

expectations <strong>of</strong> price, yield <strong>and</strong> income <strong>of</strong> farmers on their l<strong>and</strong> allocation<br />

decisions? <strong>and</strong><br />

(iii) To estimate the role <strong>of</strong> overall risk <strong>of</strong> production <strong>and</strong> consumption on the<br />

extent <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops by farmers?<br />

Sampling <strong>and</strong> Metbodology<br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> was chosen as an area <strong>of</strong> this study because <strong>of</strong> the higher<br />

importance <strong>of</strong> horticultural sector in the agricultural sector (representative in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

value <strong>of</strong> the location quotient exceeding four) <strong>and</strong> moderate to high growth in<br />

diversification toward horticultural crops over the past three decades. Shimla district <strong>and</strong><br />

Theog block has emerged out as the representative towards diversification towards<br />

horticultural crops. Due to the difference in the nature <strong>of</strong> the crops within horticultural<br />

sector, four villages were selected (two villages each for fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables) from<br />

194


Theog block, as these villages (Govai, Sainj, Shilaru <strong>and</strong> S<strong>and</strong>hu) are representatives in<br />

diversificatjon towards fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables respectively. In the first two villages namely<br />

Govai <strong>and</strong> Sainj, vegetables cover 72% <strong>and</strong> 84% <strong>of</strong> the total gross cropped area<br />

respectively. Among vegetables, most <strong>of</strong> the diversification has been towards cauliflower<br />

crop. In villages, Shilaru <strong>and</strong> S<strong>and</strong>hu, fruits are grown at a higher scale. Apple is the<br />

major crop in these villages that covers 85% <strong>and</strong> 89"10 respectively <strong>of</strong> total cultivated<br />

area. Both, cauliflower <strong>and</strong> apple crops were chosen for this stody in examining<br />

diversification <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> in favour <strong>of</strong> these horticultoral crops. Sample <strong>of</strong> 30 farm<br />

households (120 farmers in total) was drawn from each <strong>of</strong> the four villages following a<br />

stratified <strong>and</strong> proportional r<strong>and</strong>om sample approach.<br />

To address the major objectives <strong>of</strong> the stody, primary <strong>and</strong> secondary data are used.<br />

Secondary data cover 30 major crops for the past three decades across 17 states in India.<br />

By using this secondary data, the decomposition model propounded by Minhas <strong>and</strong><br />

Vaidyanathan (1965) is employed to explain agricultoral growth in tenns <strong>of</strong> both static<br />

<strong>and</strong> dynamic manner. For measuring the trend in area expansion <strong>and</strong> substitution, we<br />

have used the method by Venkataramanan <strong>and</strong> Prahladachar (1980) in measuring gross<br />

cropped area elasticities. To work out the economics <strong>of</strong> vegetable <strong>and</strong> fruit crop, different<br />

concepts are used. Farm Management Studies concepts <strong>of</strong> cost <strong>and</strong> reloms are used for<br />

examining economics <strong>of</strong> vegetable crop (cauliflower). We measured the output supply<br />

<strong>and</strong> factor dem<strong>and</strong> equations from farm level data <strong>of</strong> cauliflower using the pr<strong>of</strong>it function<br />

provided by Lau <strong>and</strong> Yotopoulos (1972). Only one variable, i.e., labour is treated as<br />

variable factor as within the given region, the prices <strong>of</strong> other factors <strong>of</strong> production i.e.,<br />

fertilizer, chemicals <strong>and</strong> irrigation do not vary across farmers. The expected price is used<br />

for measuring the pr<strong>of</strong>it due to marked difference in prices received by farmers over any<br />

single season. Net Present Value (NPV), Benefit-cost Ratio, Internal Rate <strong>of</strong> Return<br />

(IRR) <strong>and</strong> payback period are used to work out the economics <strong>of</strong> a fruit crop (apple). For<br />

the purpose <strong>of</strong> identifying the relative importance <strong>of</strong> price <strong>and</strong> production risk, the<br />

method by Barah <strong>and</strong> Binswanger (1982) is used where the gross revenue variability is<br />

decomposed into price, yield <strong>and</strong> price-yield interaction components. The method <strong>of</strong><br />

weighted mean is employed to examine the significance <strong>of</strong> economic <strong>and</strong> non-economic<br />

195


factors in diversification decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers. Source <strong>of</strong> diversity in farmers' response to<br />

change in price <strong>of</strong> cauliflower is examined by analysis <strong>of</strong> variance (ANOVA). Elicitation<br />

method is employed in obtaining the expectations <strong>of</strong> farmers <strong>of</strong> various economic<br />

outcomes from the production <strong>of</strong> the selected horticultural crops. Farmers' expectations<br />

are linked with their socio-economic <strong>and</strong> other characteristics along with their resources<br />

allocation behaviour including l<strong>and</strong> allocation. To account for the role <strong>of</strong> overall risk<br />

including production <strong>and</strong> consumption risk, we measured risk attitudes <strong>of</strong> farmers under a<br />

Safety-First framework propounded by Roy (1952). Regression method is used to<br />

examine the role <strong>of</strong> risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty on l<strong>and</strong> allocation in favour <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops<br />

by farmers.<br />

Major Conclusions<br />

At the macro (state) level, l<strong>and</strong> availability is reaching its limit <strong>and</strong> therefore little<br />

l<strong>and</strong> is available for cultivation. As a result, the role <strong>of</strong> substitution effect has been<br />

continuously increasing over a period time. This has shown that avenues <strong>of</strong> increasing<br />

growth through area increase are weak. Therefore, there is a need to look for other factors<br />

for increasing growth including crop diversification. The trend in growth rates <strong>of</strong> overall<br />

output illustrate that at the national level, growth <strong>of</strong> crop output has been highest during<br />

the decade <strong>of</strong> 19805 <strong>and</strong> that growth rate <strong>of</strong> output declined during the post 1990 period.<br />

This trend in decline <strong>of</strong> the growth rate <strong>of</strong> output during 19905 is noticed in most <strong>of</strong> the<br />

regions in India. The northern region, which benefited enormously from Green<br />

Revolution, followed a specialisation-led growth. This region experienced poor growth<br />

during the 1990s. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, southern <strong>and</strong> western regions also did not<br />

experience higher growth during 199Os.<br />

The picture is a mixed-one regarding the typologies <strong>of</strong> diversification across states.<br />

Some states exhibit high diversity in the cropping pattern but at the same time have less<br />

proportionate area under high value crops. There is also no direct link between diversity<br />

in cropping pattern <strong>and</strong> spread <strong>of</strong> crops. In terms <strong>of</strong> relationship <strong>of</strong> different components<br />

<strong>of</strong> diversification with income <strong>and</strong> risk, income growth is higher in the states that had<br />

witnessed increase spread in the cropping pattern. These states have also shifted higher<br />

196


amount <strong>of</strong> area to non-food grains. However, this effect was perceptible only during the<br />

post-liberalization period in India. Until early 199Os, states whicb followed Green<br />

Revolution strategy were the major beneficiaries, but after the onset <strong>of</strong> liberalization,<br />

these regions have performed relatively poor as compared to other states.<br />

Among the components <strong>of</strong> growth, crop diversification has indeed become an<br />

important source <strong>of</strong> growth during the post-liberalization period (1990s), <strong>and</strong> that<br />

technological development has made the largest contribution to output growth during the<br />

previous two decades. Region-wise, technological development continues to be the major<br />

component <strong>of</strong> growth for northern region, but the effect <strong>of</strong> the same has declined over a<br />

period <strong>of</strong> time. This is primarily due to decline in the yield <strong>of</strong> the specialized crops in this<br />

region. For the eastern region, area expansion continues to be the major source <strong>of</strong> growth<br />

in the absence <strong>of</strong> technological development <strong>and</strong> crop shifts. In the southern <strong>and</strong> western<br />

regions, diversification has become an important component for growth primarily due to<br />

declining area under for cultivation, non-availability <strong>of</strong> new l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> stagnation in<br />

technology development.<br />

These regions also differ in terms <strong>of</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> shift <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern over a period<br />

<strong>of</strong> time. Northern region is the only one, which through all the decades has been able to<br />

shift the crop pattern towards the crops with better technological growth. Eastern region<br />

has been able to achieve positive growth in productivity in crops towards which they had<br />

diversified during the 1990s. Western <strong>and</strong> southern regions experienced high <strong>and</strong><br />

negative dynamic effect during 199Os. This raises the concerns <strong>of</strong> lack <strong>of</strong> technological<br />

development in the crops that contributed highly towards output growth <strong>of</strong> the region.<br />

Though, there was increased shift in the crop pattern towards high value crops during<br />

1990s, the growth rate in those crop yields have dec! ined. This has resulted in the growthdepressing<br />

effect <strong>of</strong> diversification. This reflects that diversification towards high value<br />

per se is not sufficient for increasing growth but it is also important that these crops<br />

remain remunerative over a period <strong>of</strong> time, through proper technological <strong>and</strong> market<br />

development; otherwise the gains from diversification will be meagre. At aggregate level,<br />

for northern <strong>and</strong> eastern regions, it is more important to emphasis on increasing crop<br />

diversification towards high value crops that includes non-food grain crops. It is<br />

197


imperative as these regions have higher level <strong>of</strong> specialisation in rice <strong>and</strong> wheat that<br />

could have led to high vulnerability <strong>of</strong> these regions to external shocks. For southern <strong>and</strong><br />

western regions, it is more important to introduce new technology for many <strong>of</strong> the high<br />

value crops, which are becoming important sources <strong>of</strong> growth.<br />

For increasing diversification towards high value crops in India, it is vital to develop<br />

irrigation facilities. Many previous studies have argued that irrigation was not necessary<br />

for the growth <strong>of</strong> high value crops; but this can be questioned as many <strong>of</strong> the these crop<br />

are highly water-intensive <strong>and</strong> require development <strong>of</strong> irrigation as a pre-requisite.<br />

Interestingly, the regions, which have experienced higher variability in rainfall over the<br />

last three decades, could not diversitY their cropping pattern towards high value crops<br />

including non-food crops. This has affected the impact <strong>of</strong> diversification on the growth <strong>of</strong><br />

output in these specific regions. It is clear that variability in climate bas influenced the<br />

process <strong>of</strong> crop diversification <strong>and</strong> thereby the growth <strong>of</strong> output in India. The availability<br />

<strong>of</strong> number <strong>of</strong> labourers across states has significant influence on diversification towards<br />

non-food grain crops but hardly so on diversification towards rice <strong>and</strong> wheat. Evidently,<br />

non-food grain crops are highly labour intensive than rice <strong>and</strong> wheat crops.<br />

The economics <strong>of</strong> vegetable (cauliflower) <strong>and</strong> fruit (apple) crop is worked out<br />

independently keeping in view the differences in the nature <strong>of</strong> crops. In cauliflower<br />

cultivation, use <strong>of</strong> resources including fertilizer, irrigation, chemical-spray <strong>and</strong> allocation<br />

<strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> etc. to crop decreases as the farm size increases. This confirms that with the<br />

increase in farm size, farmers face more resource constraints. As the farm size increases,<br />

aggregate cost (C2) as well as paid-out cost <strong>of</strong> cauliflower production declines;<br />

consequent on this, the decline in productivity <strong>and</strong> gross <strong>and</strong> net returns occur as the farm<br />

size increases. Small farmers are able to obtain the highest productivity <strong>and</strong> returns from<br />

the cultivation <strong>of</strong> cauliflower. In order to fmd the link <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions with<br />

farm size, all farm size were divided on the basis <strong>of</strong> proportion <strong>of</strong> area under cauliflower<br />

crop in total net area. There are two categories: lower «.50) <strong>and</strong> higher (>.50) for l<strong>and</strong><br />

allocation to cauliflower. A comparison <strong>of</strong> diversified farmers within same farm size<br />

category showed that farmers with higher level <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation gained more by a<br />

decline in cost per ha as also increased net returns from the crop. This demonstrates that<br />

198


increase in l<strong>and</strong> allocation did prove remunerative <strong>and</strong> more pr<strong>of</strong>itable for all farmers<br />

irrespective <strong>of</strong> farm sizes. By using different prices <strong>and</strong> output <strong>of</strong> cauliflower, the<br />

maximum, expected <strong>and</strong> minimum net income over the paid-out cost borne by the<br />

farmers have been are computed. The result illustrates that farmers who received high<br />

income in the event <strong>of</strong> favourable market <strong>and</strong> weather conditions also lost the most when<br />

both price <strong>and</strong> production crashed. There picture <strong>of</strong> gain <strong>and</strong> loss is different, when one<br />

considers the same across different farm sizes; small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers lost the most<br />

when both the price as well as production suddenly crashed. But, medium <strong>and</strong> large<br />

farmers gained relatively more in a situation <strong>of</strong> favourable price <strong>and</strong> production<br />

conditions. It was the small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers who bore the brunt <strong>of</strong> price <strong>and</strong><br />

production crash.<br />

Efficiency analysis <strong>of</strong> cauliflower cultivation indicates that the relation between<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>it <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> is consistent with a priori notion only when price expected by farmers is<br />

used, <strong>and</strong> not on the basis <strong>of</strong> current price. This might be especially so as prices <strong>of</strong> high<br />

value crops like cauliflower fluctuate too widely <strong>and</strong> in the absence <strong>of</strong> any floor price,<br />

farmers consider only the expected price in their decision-making. The coefficient <strong>of</strong><br />

capital is high <strong>and</strong> positive. The own price elasticity <strong>of</strong> labour is greater than one in<br />

absolute value indicating an elastic response <strong>of</strong> factor utilization. On the other h<strong>and</strong>,<br />

labour dem<strong>and</strong> also responds positively to increase in endowments like l<strong>and</strong> or capital<br />

<strong>and</strong> increase in the expected price <strong>of</strong> the output. The high coefficient <strong>of</strong> capital indicates<br />

its significance on the greater use <strong>of</strong> labour with increase in capital intensiveness.<br />

Regarding the economics <strong>of</strong> apple cultivation, results illustrate that small <strong>and</strong><br />

marginal farmers have higher Net Present Value (NPV) as well as higher benefit-cost<br />

ratio <strong>of</strong> apple crop production than large farmers. However, large farmers generally have<br />

a lesser pay back period in getting returns from the crop. Large farmers also have lesser<br />

Internal Rate <strong>of</strong> Return (IRR). This points to the better position <strong>of</strong> large farmers in<br />

comparison to smaller farmers in terms <strong>of</strong> getting the total invested money back earlier.<br />

They have low discount rate which is crucial in calculating benefits from apple<br />

production. The simulation analysis presents some interesting findings: the change in<br />

price from present year price to the price expected by farmer improves the position <strong>of</strong><br />

199


small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers who are found to perform better in all four measures <strong>of</strong> cash<br />

flow analysis. Small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmer have higher NPV <strong>and</strong> Benefit-Cost ratio in<br />

addition to lower pay back period <strong>and</strong> lower discount rate. But, when it comes to the most<br />

favourable price received by the fanners, large farmers have better deal in all counts. This<br />

goes to the advantage <strong>of</strong> large farmers in terms <strong>of</strong> their better bargaining power in the<br />

market that helps them to fetch higher prices as compared to small <strong>and</strong> marginal fanner.<br />

Undoubtedly, among the economic <strong>and</strong> non-economic factors, diversification in<br />

favour <strong>of</strong> high value crops is better explained by price. It emerges as a most important<br />

factor that influences decision making as it directly affects the income potential <strong>of</strong> crop.<br />

At the same time, other non-economic factors are also significant in such decisionmaking,<br />

but their effect on a fiuit crop is different from a vegetable crop. Labour<br />

availability for <strong>and</strong> food production from the l<strong>and</strong> are critical considerations while<br />

diversifying from food to apple crop, <strong>and</strong> the significance shifts to both irrigation <strong>and</strong><br />

productivity <strong>of</strong> the crop in regard to cauliflower. This is primarily because <strong>of</strong> the critical<br />

importance <strong>of</strong> irrigation for cauliflower <strong>and</strong> its perishability compared to apple crop as<br />

influencing factors fanner's decision. Fruits can be grown in plenty in marginal areas<br />

where irrigation is not assured, whereas, fanners' inclination towards vegetable crop is<br />

received only by assured irrigation facilities, which are mostly restricted to the<br />

developed regions in India.<br />

The differences in the decision-making in diversification between fiuits <strong>and</strong><br />

vegetable crops lies in the degree <strong>of</strong> flexibility in crop, relative returns from the crops <strong>and</strong><br />

the consequence <strong>of</strong> shift <strong>of</strong> cropping pattern towards these crops on the allocation pr<strong>of</strong>ile<br />

<strong>of</strong> the farmer (higher extent <strong>of</strong> shift by apple growers make them specialize in apple,<br />

unlike in the case <strong>of</strong> cauliflower crop). For the production <strong>of</strong> cauliflower, resource<br />

availability at farm is more important for diversification decisions, unlike in the case <strong>of</strong><br />

apple, where availability <strong>of</strong> additional income source is vital. Interestingly, education is<br />

inversely related to diversification decision by farmers growing apple as such decisions<br />

are linked with increasing level <strong>of</strong> specialisation in apple cultivation due to it being a<br />

perennial crop. Educated farmers are concerned with income as well as risk in the<br />

200


Production system <strong>and</strong> hence, prefer more diversification than being fully specialized in<br />

one crop.<br />

There are a few similarities in the decision-making process <strong>of</strong> diversification<br />

towards apple <strong>and</strong> cauliflower. Relative income from the crop substantiated crop<br />

substitution decisions towards both the crops. This means that farmers take into account<br />

the aggregate gain from the crop in their decision rather than depending solely on the<br />

price signals. Their capacity to generate higher productivity <strong>and</strong> better market prospects<br />

together explain fanners' decisions. Thus, intervention in the technology <strong>and</strong> markets are<br />

concomitantly required than only harping on market improvement for increasing l<strong>and</strong> in<br />

favour <strong>of</strong>horticulturai crops.<br />

Expectation about different economic outcomes reflects farmer behaviour<br />

(pertaining to l<strong>and</strong> allocation) in response to uncertainty. In regard to price, there exists a<br />

huge difference in the expectations among the horticultural producers <strong>and</strong> the same is<br />

found influenced by the levels <strong>of</strong> price received by them over a period <strong>of</strong> time.<br />

Improvement in the market infrastructure enables the farmers to realize price prevailing<br />

in the large economy. This is likely to influence the price expectations in a positive<br />

manner. Higher price expectations improve the input-use propensity <strong>of</strong> farmers in tenns<br />

<strong>of</strong> higher intensity <strong>of</strong> labour, more willingness to pay for hired labour <strong>and</strong> be more<br />

willing to reinvest pr<strong>of</strong>its in l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> crop related activities. However, for l<strong>and</strong> allocation,<br />

income expectations are vital. In other words, price expectation alone cannot explain the<br />

l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions <strong>of</strong> the farmer, but, output per ha is more important. Price<br />

expectations are important but it has relatively less role in allocation <strong>of</strong> inelastic factors<br />

<strong>of</strong> production, i.e., l<strong>and</strong>. It is income expectations <strong>of</strong> the farmers that are more critical in<br />

determining the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions. This explain that, though it is important to<br />

build a market structure in order to influence better input-use propensities <strong>of</strong> farmers, the<br />

same is insufficient for improving fanners' orientation to increase the inelastic factor <strong>of</strong><br />

production i.e., l<strong>and</strong> in favour <strong>of</strong> high value crops.<br />

The results <strong>of</strong> risk decomposition <strong>of</strong> income risk into pnce, yield <strong>and</strong> their<br />

interactions show a stark difference in apple <strong>and</strong> cauliflower crop. 52 <strong>of</strong> the 60 apple<br />

201


growing farmers experiences high variability in yield <strong>of</strong> the crop as compared to price<br />

variability, whereas majority <strong>of</strong> cauliflower growers experiences high price variabi!ity<br />

than yield (32 out <strong>of</strong> 60). In addition, the major beneficiaries <strong>of</strong> reduced price variability<br />

are cauliflower grower <strong>and</strong> not apple growers. Stabilizing the yield <strong>of</strong> the crop would be<br />

much more effective in stabilizing revenues <strong>of</strong> apple whereas stabilizing price, on the<br />

other h<strong>and</strong>, is more effective strategy to reduce revenue risk <strong>of</strong> cauliflower growers. In<br />

addition, there is a positive correlation between price <strong>and</strong> production <strong>of</strong> apple, whereas it<br />

is negative in the case <strong>of</strong> cauliflower. This shows that apple growers who receive higher<br />

level <strong>of</strong> production have also been able to receive higher price <strong>of</strong> crop. This is mainly<br />

because they were able to sell their produce in different forms <strong>and</strong> at different <strong>and</strong> far <strong>of</strong>f<br />

markets like Delhi, Ahmedabad etc. Lack <strong>of</strong> such opportunity for vegetable marketing is<br />

partially responsible for the negative correlation between production <strong>and</strong> price.<br />

Coming to the role <strong>of</strong> overall risk including that <strong>of</strong> production <strong>and</strong> consumption in<br />

l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions, farmers, who have allocated less l<strong>and</strong> proportion as <strong>of</strong> a total<br />

net cropped area to cauliflower or apple, seem to have lower level <strong>of</strong> disaster income.<br />

This indicates that food consumption <strong>and</strong> other requirements like schooling <strong>of</strong> the<br />

children, other responsibilities etc, also have a role in l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions by<br />

farmers. Interestingly, these farmers gets lower net income from the crop as compared to<br />

farmers who have diversified more in terms <strong>of</strong> allocating larger proportion <strong>of</strong> area to<br />

cauliflower <strong>and</strong> apple. More interestingly, highly diversified farmers experienced less<br />

variance in the net crop income. Due to higher income <strong>and</strong> lower food consumption<br />

requirements <strong>and</strong> low variance, farmers with higher diversification have performed better<br />

in terms <strong>of</strong> Safety-First position. It means that the overall risk <strong>of</strong> consumption <strong>and</strong><br />

production did playa significant role in explaining the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions.<br />

Policy ImplicatioDs<br />

The specific policy implications <strong>of</strong> the results are as follows:<br />

I. <strong>Diversification</strong> indeed has become an important source <strong>of</strong> agricultural growth in<br />

India. Increased significance <strong>of</strong> diversification towards high value crops in output<br />

202


growth is accompanied by the slow productivity growth <strong>of</strong> high value crops. There<br />

is need to emphasize on government intervention in the techn~logy development <strong>of</strong><br />

high value crops in India which was otherwise being neglected by the policy<br />

makers. <strong>Diversification</strong> towards high value crops per se, is not sufficient for<br />

indUCing growth but it is also important that these crops remain remunerative over a<br />

period <strong>of</strong> time. That requires proper technological <strong>and</strong> market development,<br />

otherwise the gains from diversification will be negligible.<br />

2. Both economic <strong>and</strong> non-economic factors influence farmers' decision <strong>of</strong><br />

reallocation <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> from food crops to high value commercial crops. Irrigation is<br />

vital for diversification towards vegetable crops, whereas availability <strong>of</strong> labour is<br />

crucial for diversification towards fiuit crops. Therefore, there is a need for distinct<br />

policies for fiuits <strong>and</strong> vegetable sectors. Policy makers need to account for<br />

differences in the nature <strong>of</strong> the crops while designing policies for enhancing<br />

diversification towards horticultural crops.<br />

3. Development <strong>and</strong> integration <strong>of</strong> markets are vital to increase farmer's welfare. High<br />

price expectations are positively linked with the prices received by fanners over a<br />

period <strong>of</strong> time. Though it is dependant on market structure <strong>and</strong> integration. High<br />

price expectations by farmers directly influence their input use behaviour in<br />

addition to improving the aggregate productivity <strong>and</strong> output at fann level.<br />

Additionally, better market integration influences the net focused gain by the<br />

fanners which in tum affects farmers' decision <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> allocation towards high<br />

value crops.<br />

4. While, taking the l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions, farmers attach more importance to<br />

expected total net income from the crop <strong>and</strong> hence consider both the price <strong>and</strong> yield<br />

in their decision-making. Relative incomes from the crops explain the crop<br />

substitution decisions <strong>of</strong> farmers i.e., fanners calculate the aggregate gain from the<br />

crop than consider only the price <strong>of</strong> crop. The capacity to generate higher<br />

productivity <strong>and</strong> availability <strong>of</strong> better marketing prospects together explains<br />

farmers' decision. Thus, intervention in production technology <strong>and</strong> streamlining<br />

markets are concomitantly required; harping on market improvement for increasing<br />

l<strong>and</strong> in favour <strong>of</strong> horticultural crops will not suffice.<br />

203


5. Price stabilization is more important for vegetable crops than fruit crops primarily<br />

due to the higher level <strong>of</strong> perishability <strong>and</strong>. lack <strong>of</strong> marketing options for vegetable<br />

crops. A policy <strong>of</strong> price stabilization will be more effective to increase farmers'<br />

orientation towards allocating more area to vegetable crops, whereas, for fruits,<br />

yield stabilization is more important.<br />

6. Farmers are concerned not only about crop-specific risk but also about their<br />

aggregate production <strong>and</strong> consumption risk. So improving farmers' orientation<br />

towards high value crops require intervention in food grain markets by improving<br />

the technology. Better technology in food crop can lead to increase in the<br />

productivity <strong>of</strong> food crops which would help in reducing consumption constraints<br />

for higher allocation <strong>of</strong>l<strong>and</strong> to high value non-food crops. In addition, development<br />

<strong>of</strong> labour market can be critical for l<strong>and</strong> allocation decisions by farmers as it would<br />

help farmers to earn more income <strong>and</strong> alleviate income constraints for<br />

diversification.<br />

204


References <strong>and</strong> Selected Bibliography<br />

Acharya 5.5., 2003. Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> in Indian Agriculture. Agricultural Situation in India. Vol. LX,<br />

No.5, August 2003, New Delhi.<br />

----------, 2004. Agricultural Marketing. Vol. 17, State <strong>of</strong> the Indian Farmer: A Millennium Study.<br />

Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Cooperation, MinistIy <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, Government <strong>of</strong> India. New<br />

Delhi.<br />

Agarwal I., 2004. Rationale <strong>of</strong> Resource Use through Farm diversification. Agricultural &onomics<br />

Research Review. VoU7, Vol. I. pp. 85-100.<br />

Alagh M., <strong>and</strong> Y.K.Alagh, 2003. Trends in Crop <strong>Diversification</strong>: Need for a Policy Shift. Agricultural<br />

Situation in India. Vol. LX, No.5, August 2003, New Delhi.<br />

Alagh, Y.K. <strong>and</strong> P.S. Sharma, 1980. Growth <strong>of</strong> Crop Production: 1960-61 to 1978-79- Is it decelerating?,<br />

Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics, Vol. 35, No 2, pp.104-1 18.<br />

Arrow KJ., 1951. Alternative Approaches to the Theory <strong>of</strong> Choice in Risk Taking Situations.<br />

Econometrica. Vol. 19, No.4, pp. 404-437<br />

---------, 1971. Essays in the Theory <strong>of</strong> Risk Bearing. Amsterdam, North Holl<strong>and</strong>.<br />

Askari H. <strong>and</strong> J.T Cummings,1976. Supply Response <strong>of</strong> Farmers with Heterogeneous L<strong>and</strong>. Indian Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> Agricultural &onomics, Vol 31, No.1, pp 13-22<br />

Atwood J.A, M.J Watts, GA Helmers <strong>and</strong> L.J Held, 1988. Incorporating Safety First Constraints in Linear<br />

Programming Production Models. Western Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 13, No. J. pp. 29-<br />

36<br />

Azad K.C, R Swarp <strong>and</strong> B.K Sikka, 1998. <strong>Horticultural</strong> Development in Hill Areas. Mittal Publications.<br />

New Delhi<br />

Barah B.C, <strong>and</strong> H. Binswanger, 1982. Regional Effects <strong>of</strong> National Stabilisation Policies: The <strong>Case</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

India, Progress Reports No. 37, IeR/SAT Economics Program. Patancheru, India.<br />

Barghouti S., <strong>and</strong> M. Petit, 1992. <strong>Diversification</strong>: Cballenges <strong>and</strong> Opportunities. In Barghouti S., L.<br />

Garbus, <strong>and</strong> D. Umali, 1992. Trends in Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong>: Regional Perspectives. World<br />

Bank Technical PaperNo. 180. The World Bank, Washington DC.<br />

Barghouti 5., S. Kane, K. Sorby <strong>and</strong> M. Ali, 2004. Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong> for the Poor, Agriculture<br />

<strong>and</strong> Rural Development (ARO) Discussion Paper No. I ARD Department, World Bank, Washington<br />

DC<br />

Barrett C.B, <strong>and</strong> T. Reardon, 2000. Asset, Activity <strong>and</strong> Income <strong>Diversification</strong> among African<br />

Agriculturalists: Some Practical Issues. http://ssm.comlabstract~257344<br />

Barrett C.B, M Bezuneh, D.C Clay <strong>and</strong> T Reardon, 2000. Heterogeneous Constraints,<br />

Income <strong>Diversification</strong> Strategies in Rural<br />

http://aem.comell.eduifaculty siteslcbb2lpapers/BBCR May2004.pdf<br />

Incentives <strong>and</strong><br />

Africa.<br />

Barrett C.B, M Bezuneh, <strong>and</strong> A. Aboud, 2001. Income diversification, Poverty Traps <strong>and</strong> Policy Shocks in<br />

Cote d' Ivoire <strong>and</strong> Kenya. Food Policy, Vol. 26, pp. 367-384<br />

205


Behrman J.R, 1968. Supply Response in Underdeveloped Agriculture: A Coae Study <strong>of</strong> Four Major Annual<br />

<strong>Crops</strong> in Thai/aNi 1937-1963. Amsterdam, North Holl<strong>and</strong><br />

Benziger V., 1996. Small field, Big Money: Two Successful Programs in Helping Small Farmers Make the<br />

Transition to High Value-Added <strong>Crops</strong>. World Development, Vol 24, No.1 1. pp 1681-1693<br />

Bevan D.L, P Collier, <strong>and</strong> J.W Gunning, 1991. Income <strong>and</strong> Substitution Effects in Models <strong>of</strong> Supply<br />

Response Under Rationing. Oxford Economic Papers. Vol. 43 No.2. pp.340-343<br />

Bhalla G.s <strong>and</strong> G. Singh, 2001. Indian Agriculture: Four Decades <strong>of</strong> Development. Sage Publications,<br />

New Delhi<br />

Bhatia, M.S. <strong>and</strong> R.C. Sinha, 1975. Growth Rates <strong>and</strong> Relative Contribution <strong>of</strong> Different Components<br />

towards Total Food grain Production in Uttar <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Agricultural Situation in India, Vol. 30, N09,<br />

pp. 629-631.<br />

Bhatia, M.S., 1979. Changing Pattern <strong>of</strong> Resource Structure <strong>and</strong> Dem<strong>and</strong> for Inputs in Indian Agriculture,<br />

Agricultural Situation in India. Vol. 34, No.7, pp. 435-439.<br />

Binswanger H.P., 1981. Attitudes toward Risk: Theoretical Implications <strong>of</strong> an Experiment in Rural India<br />

The Economic Journal Vo1.91, (December) pp. 867-90<br />

Binswanger H.P., <strong>and</strong> J.V. Braun, 1991. Technological Change <strong>and</strong> Commercialization in Agriculture: The<br />

Effect on the Poor. The World Bank Research Observer, Vol.6, No.1 Jan, 1991.57-80.<br />

Birtbal P.S., P.K. Joshi <strong>and</strong> A. Gulati, 2005. Vertical Coordination in High Value Food Commodities.<br />

Implications for Smallholders. MTID Discussion poper no. 85, April 2005, IFPRI, Washington DC.<br />

Birtbal P.S, <strong>and</strong> P.K Joshi, 2007. Institutional Innovations for Improving Smallholder Participation in<br />

High-Value Agriculture: A <strong>Case</strong> <strong>of</strong> Fruit <strong>and</strong> Vegetable Growers' Association in India. Quarterly<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> International Agriculture. Vol. 46, No.1. pp. 49-68<br />

Birthal P.S, P.K Joshi, D Roy <strong>and</strong> A Thorat, 2007. <strong>Diversification</strong> in Indian Agriculture towards High<br />

Value <strong>Crops</strong>: The Role <strong>of</strong> Smallholders. IFPRI Discussion Paper No. 727, IFPRI Washington D.C.<br />

http://www,ifuri.orglpubsidp/ifpridpOO727.asp<br />

Bisalliah S., 1977 Decomposition Analysis <strong>of</strong> Output Change under New Production Technology in Wheat<br />

Farming: Some Implications to Returns on Research Investment. Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural<br />

Economics, Vol 23, No.3, pp. 193-201.<br />

-------------, 1978. Decomposition Analysis <strong>of</strong> Employment Change under new Production Technology in<br />

Punjab Agriculture. Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics, Vol 33, No.2, pp. 70-80<br />

Blank S.C. 1990. Returns to Limited Crop <strong>Diversification</strong>. Western Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics.<br />

Vol. 15, No.2. pp. 204-212<br />

------------, 2006. Cullivar Diversity as a Risk Management Strategy for Tree Crop Growers.<br />

http://www.agecon.ucdavis.eduJextensionluodateiarticlesiv7n6 2.odf<br />

Boussard I.M <strong>and</strong> M. Petit, 1967. Representation <strong>of</strong> Farmers' Behaviour under Uncertainty with a Focus­<br />

Loss Constraint. Journal <strong>of</strong> Farm Economics. Vol. 49, No.4, pp. 869-880<br />

206


Braun J.V, 1995. Agricultural Commercialization: Impacts on Income <strong>and</strong> Nutrition <strong>and</strong> Implications for<br />

Policy. Food Policy. Vol 20, No.3, pp 187-202<br />

Buschena, DE. & D. Zilberman, 1994. What Do We Know About Decision Making Under Risk <strong>and</strong><br />

Where Do We Go From Here? Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural <strong>and</strong> Resource Economics. Vol. 19, No.2, pp.<br />

425-444<br />

Castle E.N, 1954. Flexibility <strong>and</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> as a Means <strong>of</strong> Meeting Price <strong>and</strong> Yield Uncertainty in<br />

Western Kansas. Journal <strong>of</strong> Farm &onomics. Vol. 36 No.2. pp.273-284<br />

Cauvey, R., 1991. Groundnut Production in Tamil Nadu - A Decomposition Analysis, Agricultural<br />

SitUl1lion in India, Vol. 46, No.5, pp. 321-324.<br />

Centre for Monitoring Indian Economy (CMIE), Economic Intelligence Service, 2009.<br />

http://www.cmie.com<br />

Ch<strong>and</strong> R. <strong>and</strong> J.L Kaul,1986. A Note on the Use <strong>of</strong> the Cobb-Douglas Pr<strong>of</strong>it Function. American Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Agricultural Economics, Vol 68, No.3, pp. 162-164.<br />

Ch<strong>and</strong> R., 1996. Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Development <strong>of</strong> Mountain Regions with Special<br />

Reference to <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>. Kalyani publishers, New Delhi<br />

--.------, 1996. Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Farm <strong>and</strong> Non-Farm Employment in <strong>Himachal</strong><br />

<strong>Pradesh</strong>. Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Labour Economics, VoL39, No.4, pp. 841-852.<br />

-----, 1996. <strong>Diversification</strong> Through High Value <strong>Crops</strong> in Western Himalayan Region: Evidence<br />

from <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>. Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural &onomics. VoLS!, No.4, pp. 652-663.<br />

------, 1996. Ecological <strong>and</strong> Economic Impact <strong>of</strong> HorticulturaJ Development in the Himalayas:<br />

Evidence from <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>. Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, June 29, 1996. pp. A93-A99<br />

-----------, 2004. Impact <strong>of</strong> Trade Liberalisation <strong>and</strong> related Reforms on India's Agricultural Sector,<br />

Rural Food Security, Income <strong>and</strong> Poverty.<br />

http://www.gdnet.org/cms.php?id-research Daper ahstract&research DaDer id-I0280<br />

------------, 2005. Exploring Possibilities <strong>of</strong> Achieving Four Percent Growth Rate in Indian Agriculture.<br />

www.ncap.res.inlupload files/others/oth 7.pdf<br />

----------, 2006. Farm Income in India: Past, Present <strong>and</strong> Future. In Macro-Economic Policy,<br />

Agricultural Development <strong>and</strong> Rural Institutions. National Conference in Honour <strong>of</strong> Pr<strong>of</strong>. A<br />

Vaidyanathan, 09-10 April, 2006. ISEC, Bangalore.<br />

Ch<strong>and</strong> R. <strong>and</strong> S. Chauhan, 2002. Socio-Economic Factors in Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong> in India.<br />

Agricultural Situation in India. Vol. 10, No.3, February 2002, New Delhi.<br />

Ch<strong>and</strong>, K.P, R. Singh <strong>and</strong> M.L Sharma. 1986. <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>of</strong> Agriculture in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> - A<br />

Spatio-Temporal Analysis,Agricultural Situation in India, Vol. 41, No.5, pp. 451-460.<br />

Ch<strong>and</strong>rakar, M.R. <strong>and</strong> A.K. Koshta, 1997. Contribution <strong>of</strong> Relative Factors in the Growth <strong>of</strong> Productivity<br />

<strong>and</strong> Production <strong>of</strong> <strong>Crops</strong> in Chattisgarh Plains: A Component Analysis, Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural<br />

Economics, Vol. 52, No.3, pp. 444-445.<br />

207


Chaplin H, 2000. Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong>: A Review <strong>of</strong> Methodological Approaches <strong>and</strong> Empirical<br />

Evidence. www.agp.uni-honn.delagpoJrsrch/idara/Fann/wvewp2.doc<br />

Conlon l.R, 1990. Pr<strong>of</strong>it, Supply <strong>and</strong> Factor Dem<strong>and</strong> Functions: A Comment. American Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Agricultural Economics, Vol 72, No.2, pp. 488-492<br />

Cummings J.T, 1975. The Supply Responsiveness <strong>of</strong> Indian Fanners in the Post-Independent Period.<br />

Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural &onomics, Vol 30, No.1, pp 25-40.<br />

De, U.K., 2000. <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>of</strong> Crop in West Bengal: A Spatio-Temporal Analysis, Art/Ill Vijnana, Vol.<br />

42, No2, pp. 170-182.<br />

-----, 2005, Economics <strong>of</strong> Crop <strong>Diversification</strong>- An Analysis <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Allocation towards Different<br />

<strong>Crops</strong>. http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.del78681lIMPRA paper 7868.pdf<br />

Delgado C.L <strong>and</strong> l. W.Mellor, 1984. A Strucutralist View <strong>of</strong> Policy Issues in African Agricultural<br />

Development. American Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 66 pp. 665~70<br />

Delgado C.L, 1995. Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Export Promotion in Sub-Saharan Mrica. Food<br />

Policy. Vol. 20, No.3, pp. 225-243.<br />

Delgado c.L., <strong>and</strong> A Siamwalla, 1997. Rural Economy <strong>and</strong> Farm Income <strong>Diversification</strong> in Developing<br />

Countries. Market <strong>and</strong> Structural Studies Division (MSSD) Discussion Paper No.20, IFPRI,<br />

Washington DC.<br />

Deodhar S., Y.M. L<strong>and</strong>es <strong>and</strong> B. Kriss<strong>of</strong>f, 2006. Prospects for India's Emerging Apple Market. FTS-319-<br />

01. &anomie Research Service, U.S. Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture.<br />

Dercon S., 1996. Risk, Crop Choice <strong>and</strong> Savings: Evidence from Tanzania. Economic Development <strong>and</strong><br />

Cultural Change. Vol.44, No.3. pp. 485-513<br />

Deshp<strong>and</strong>e R.S <strong>and</strong> H. Ch<strong>and</strong>rashekar 1980. Growth <strong>and</strong> Supply Response <strong>of</strong> Slow Growth <strong>Crops</strong>: A <strong>Case</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong> Pulses. Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol 37, N03, July-Sep, 1980.<br />

Deshp<strong>and</strong>e R.S, 1985. Yield Uncertainty in Maharasbtra Agriculture: A Study with Special Reference to<br />

Drought Prone Areas. Thesis submitted 10 Department <strong>of</strong> Economics, Marathwada University,<br />

Aurangabad.<br />

-----------, 1996. Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Supply <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Commodities- A Review. Indian Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Agricultural Economics. Vol 51, No.1. pp. 270-287<br />

Deshp<strong>and</strong>e R.S., M.J. Bhende, P. Thippaiah, <strong>and</strong> M. Vivekan<strong>and</strong>a, 2004. <strong>Crops</strong> <strong>and</strong> Cultivation. Vol. 9,<br />

State <strong>of</strong> the Indian Farmer: A Millennium Study. Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Cooperation, Ministry<br />

<strong>of</strong> Agriculture, Government <strong>of</strong> India. New Delhi.<br />

Dey A K, 1977. Green Revolution Contrasts: Rice <strong>and</strong> Wheat. Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, June 4<br />

1977. pp.921-925<br />

Diop N. <strong>and</strong> S. Jaffee, 2005. Fruits <strong>and</strong> Vegetables: Global Trade <strong>and</strong> Competition in Fresh <strong>and</strong> Processed<br />

Product Markets. In Ataman Aksoy <strong>and</strong> J Beghin (eds). Global Agricultural Trade <strong>and</strong> Developing<br />

Countries. World Bank, Washington D.C.<br />

208


Egerton A.D, 1956. The holding <strong>of</strong> Assets: 'Gambler Preference' or 'Safety First'. Oxford Economic<br />

Papers, New Series. Vol.8, No.1, pp.51-59<br />

Eisa H.M, 1987. Upstream needs: Information, Inputs <strong>and</strong> Credit. In Davis TJ <strong>and</strong> IA Schirmer (eds.).<br />

Sustainability issues in Agricultural Development. 1987 Proceedings <strong>of</strong> the Seventh Agriculture Sector<br />

Symposium. World Bank, Washington DC<br />

Ernran M.S <strong>and</strong> F. Shilpi 2007. The Extent <strong>of</strong> the Market <strong>and</strong> Stages <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Specialisation. The<br />

World Bank, Development Research Group, Policy Research Working paper No- WP4534<br />

Ersado L, 2003. Income <strong>Diversification</strong> in Zimbabwe: Welfare Implications from Urban <strong>and</strong> Rural Areas.<br />

FCND Discussion paper No 152, IFPRI, Washington DC<br />

Evans,H.E. <strong>and</strong> P.Ngau. 1991. "Rural-Urban Relations, Household Income <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Agricultural<br />

Productivity." Development <strong>and</strong> Change. Vol. 22, No.1 :519-545.<br />

Evenson RE, CE Pray <strong>and</strong> M.W Rosegrant, 1999. Agricultural Research <strong>and</strong> Productivity Growth in<br />

India. Research Report 109. Washington DC.IFPRl<br />

Ezekiel M., 1938. The Cobweb Theorem. TIre Quarterly Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics. Vol. 52, No.2, pp. 255-280<br />

Fafcharnps M, 1992. Casherop Production, Food Price Volatility, <strong>and</strong> Rural Market Integration in the<br />

Third World. Americanjournal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 74, No.1. pp. 90-99<br />

Fisher M.R, 1961. Towards a Theory <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong>. Chiford Economic Papers, Vol. 13, No.3, pp. 293·<br />

311<br />

Frances G, I Latron <strong>and</strong> J. Rosell, 2000. The Measurement <strong>of</strong> On-Farm <strong>Diversification</strong>.<br />

http://www.ersa.org/ersaconfslersaOO/odf-ersalodfl245.pdf<br />

Ghosh B. <strong>and</strong> P. De, 2005. India Infrastructure database, 2005: Vol I & ll. Bookwell Publishers, New<br />

Delhi.<br />

Goletti F, 1999. Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Rural Industrialization as a Strategy for Rural Income<br />

Growth <strong>and</strong> Poverty Reduction in Indochina <strong>and</strong> Myanmar. Mar/cets <strong>and</strong> Structural Studies Division<br />

(MSS) Discussion Paper No. 30, IFPRI, Washington D.C<br />

Gonzales L.A. 1984. An Economic Perspective <strong>of</strong> Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> in Rainfed Areas: Implications to<br />

National <strong>and</strong> Regional Planning. TIre Philippine Journal <strong>of</strong> Crop Science, Vol 9, No.2, 1984<br />

Government <strong>of</strong> <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>, 2008. Annual Season <strong>and</strong> Crop Report (Various issues). Directorate <strong>of</strong><br />

L<strong>and</strong> Records, Shimla, HP<br />

------------------------, 2008. Directorate <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, Shimla, <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> (HP),<br />

India<br />

(HP),lndia<br />

2008. Directorate <strong>of</strong> Horticulture, Shimla, <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong><br />

____________________________ . ____________ , 2008. Directorate <strong>of</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Records, Shimla, <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong><br />

(HP),lndia<br />

209


------------•.. --- 2007. Statistical Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> (Various issues).<br />

Directorate <strong>of</strong> Economics <strong>and</strong> Statistics, Shimla, <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> (HP).<br />

--.----.-.-.-------, 2007. Shimla Marice!, Dhalli, Shlmla, <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong> (HP),<br />

India<br />

Government <strong>of</strong> India, 2005. Agricultural Statistics at a Glance, 2005, Ministry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, New Delhi,<br />

India<br />

-.--.----•.. -., 2006. Area <strong>and</strong> Production <strong>of</strong> Principal <strong>Crops</strong> in India (Various Issues). Ministry<br />

<strong>of</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Cooperation, New Deihl, India<br />

.---.----.••.. -, 2005, Central Statistical Organization (CSO), National Accounts Statistics, New<br />

Deihl.<br />

- .. --•. -----, 2007 Economic Survey (Various issues), Ministry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, New Delhi,<br />

India<br />

-.-.... -----.... , 2007. Fertilizer Statistics (Various Issues). Ministry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, New Delhi,<br />

India<br />

--.-.--.-.--... , 2006. Indian Agricultural Statistics (Various Issues). Ministry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, New<br />

Delhi, India<br />

----.... --... -, 2006. Indian Labour Statistics (Various Issues). Ministry <strong>of</strong> Labour. New Delhi,<br />

India<br />

- •• ---•• ---.-.• -, 2008. National <strong>Horticultural</strong> Board (Various Issues), New Delhi, India<br />

.-.. - .. - .. - .. - .... - ... , 2006. Statistical Abstract India (Various Issues). Central Statistical Organisation,<br />

Ministry <strong>of</strong> Statistics <strong>and</strong> Programme Implementation, New Deihl, India<br />

Gregson M.E, 1993. Rural Response to Increased Dem<strong>and</strong>: Crop Choice in the Mid·West, 1860-1880. The<br />

Journal o/Economic History, Vol. 53, No.2. pp. 332-345<br />

- •••••••.•. - •••• , 1994. Strategies for Commercialization: Missouri Agriculture, 1860-1880. The Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Economic History, Vol. 54, No.2. pp. 423425<br />

- ...... ----.. , 1996. Long·Tenn Trends in Agricultural Specialisation in the United States. Agricultural<br />

History, Vo1.70, No.1. pp 90-101<br />

Grimes W.E, 1929. <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>of</strong> Agriculture. Its Limitations <strong>and</strong> its Advantages. Annals 0/ the<br />

American Academy 0/ Political <strong>and</strong> Social Science, Vol. 42, Fann Relief (March, 1929). pp 2 I 6·221<br />

Grisley W, <strong>and</strong> E.D. Kellogg, 1983. Fanners' Subjective Probabilities in Northern Thail<strong>and</strong>: An Elicitation<br />

Analysis. American Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural EconomiCS, Vo1.65, No.1. pp74-82<br />

Grosskopf S, K. Hayes <strong>and</strong> S Yaisawamg, 1992. Measuring Economics <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong>: A Frontier<br />

Approach. Journal o/Business <strong>and</strong> Economics Statistics. Vol. 10. No.4, pp. 453459<br />

Gulati A <strong>and</strong> T. Kelley, 1999. Trade Liberalization <strong>and</strong> Indian Agriculture. Oxford University Press, New<br />

Delhi<br />

2\0


Gupta, R.P. <strong>and</strong> S.K. Tewari, 1985. Factors Affecting Crop <strong>Diversification</strong>: An Empirical Analysis, Indian<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics, Yo. 40, No3. pp. 304-309.<br />

Gupta S.C <strong>and</strong> A. Majid, 1965. Producers' Response to clU1nge in Prices <strong>and</strong> Policies: A <strong>Case</strong> Study <strong>of</strong><br />

Sugarcane <strong>and</strong> Paddy in Eastern UNar <strong>Pradesh</strong>. Agro-Economic Resemch Centre, University <strong>of</strong><br />

Delhi, Delhi.<br />

Guyer J.I, 1996. Diversity at Different Levels: Farm <strong>and</strong> Community in Western Nigeria. Africa: Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

the International African Institute, Vol. 66, No. \. pp. 77-89<br />

Haque T., 1996. Small Farm <strong>Diversification</strong>: Problems <strong>and</strong> Prospects, National Centre for Agricultural<br />

Economics <strong>and</strong> Policy Research (NCAP) Workshop Proceedings I, New Delhi, March 1996<br />

Hardaker J_B, 2000. Some Issues in Dealing with Risk in Agriculture. Working paper series in Agricultwal<br />

<strong>and</strong> Resource Economics. No. 2000-3- March 2000.<br />

www.ageconsearch.umn.edulbilstreamlI29l2l1/wpOOOQQ3.pdf<br />

Hazell P., 1987. Economics Policy for Di versi ficalion. In Davis T.J <strong>and</strong> I.A Schirmer (eds .). Sustainability<br />

Issues in Agricultural Development. 1987 Proceedings <strong>of</strong> the Seventh Agriculture Sector Symposium.<br />

World Bank, Washington DC<br />

Hazra c.R., 2003. Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>of</strong> Agriculture in India Agricultural Situation in India. Vol. LX,<br />

No.5, August 2003, New Delhi.<br />

Heady E.O., 1952. <strong>Diversification</strong> in Resource Allocation <strong>and</strong> Minimization <strong>of</strong> Ineome Variability. Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> Farm Economics. Vol. 34, No.4. pp. 482-496<br />

------------,1962. Economics <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Production <strong>and</strong> Resource Use. Prentice-Hall, Inc. New<br />

Jersey, USA.<br />

Held LJ <strong>and</strong> R.A Zink 1982. Farm Enterprise Choice: Risk-Return Trade<strong>of</strong>fs for Cash-Crop versus Crop­<br />

Livestock Systems. North Central Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 4, No.2 pp. 11-19<br />

Huffman WE, <strong>and</strong> RE Evenson, 2oo\. Structural <strong>and</strong> Productivity Change in US Agriculture: 1950-82.<br />

Agricultural Economics. Vol. 24 (2001): 127-147<br />

images, Google, 2009. www.images.google.co.in<br />

imminck D.C <strong>and</strong> J.A Alarcon, 1993. Household Income, Food Availability, <strong>and</strong> Commercial Crop<br />

Production by Smallholder Farmers in the Western Highl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>of</strong> Gautemala. Economic Development<br />

<strong>and</strong> Cultural Change. Vol.41 , No.2. pp. 319-342<br />

Indiastal, 2007. http://www.Indiastal.com.<br />

Jamal, H. <strong>and</strong> A. Zaman, 1992. Decomposition <strong>of</strong> Growth Trend in Agriculture: Another Approach, Indian<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 47, No.4, pp. 644-65\.<br />

Janvry A.D. M Fafcharnps <strong>and</strong> E Sadoulet, 199\. Peasant Household Behaviour with Missing Markets:<br />

Some Paradoxes Explained. The Economic Journal. Vol. 101. NoA09. pp. 1400-1417<br />

Jayne T.S, 1994. Do High Food Marketing Costs Constrain Cash Crop Production? Evidence from<br />

Zimbabwe. Economic Development <strong>and</strong> Cultural Change, Vol. 42, No.2. pp. 387-402<br />

211


Johnson J.B., <strong>and</strong> G W Brester, 2001. Economics Consideration <strong>of</strong> Exp<strong>and</strong>ing Crop Rotations. Briefing<br />

Paper No.5. Agricultural Marketing Policy Centre, Montana State University.<br />

httD://agecon.uwyo.edulRiskMgtlPrnduetionRisklPRODUCTIONDEF AUL T.htm<br />

Johnson, S.R, 1967. A Re-examination <strong>of</strong>tbe Farm Diversifieation Problem. Journal <strong>of</strong> Farm Economics,<br />

Vol. 49 No.3 pp. 61 ()'62 I<br />

Joshi P.K., 2001. <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>of</strong> Agriculture in More Competitive Environment. Report <strong>of</strong> the APO<br />

Study Meeting on Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> International Competitiveness, Tokyo, 16-23 May<br />

2001<br />

-------, 2005. Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> in India: Nature, Pattern <strong>and</strong> Drivers, National Centre for<br />

Agricultural Economics <strong>and</strong> Policy Research, New Delhi.<br />

http://www.adb.org/DocumentsIReportsiConsultantffAR-IND-4066/Agricultureijoshi.pdf<br />

Joshi P.K., A. Gulati, P.S. Birthal, <strong>and</strong> P.P Rao, 2004. Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Vertical Integration<br />

in India: Will Smallholders Participate? MlTD Discussion Paper, IFPRJ, Washington D.C<br />

Joshi, P.K., A. Gulati, P.S. Birthal <strong>and</strong> L. Tewari. 2004. "Agriculture <strong>Diversification</strong> in South Asia:<br />

Patterns, Determinants, <strong>and</strong> Policy Implications". Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, Vol 39, No.24, pp<br />

2457-2468<br />

Joshi, PIC, PS, Birthal <strong>and</strong> N. Minot, 2006. Sources <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Growth in India: Role <strong>of</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

towards High Value <strong>Crops</strong>. MTID Discussion Paper No. 98, IFPRJ, Washington D.C.<br />

Just R.E, 1974. An Investigation <strong>of</strong> the Importance <strong>of</strong> Risk in Farmers' Decisions. American Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Agricultural Economics, Vol. 56, pp.l4-25<br />

Kalamkar S.S, 2005. Agricultural Development <strong>and</strong> Source <strong>of</strong> Output Growth in Maharashtra State.<br />

http://www.gioe.ernet.inlworking%20paoerlkalamkar working%200aoer.pdf<br />

Kaul, J.L. <strong>and</strong> R.K. Sondhi, 1971. Growth <strong>of</strong> Agriculture in Punjab - An Analysis by Component<br />

Elements, Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural &anomies, Vol. 26, No.6, PI'. 407-409.<br />

Key N, E Sadoulet <strong>and</strong> A D Janvry, 2000. Transaction Costs <strong>and</strong> Agricultural Household Supply Response.<br />

American Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 82, No.2 Pl'. 245-259<br />

Khan M.H <strong>and</strong> D R. Maki, 1979. Effects <strong>of</strong> Farm Size on Economic Efficiency: The <strong>Case</strong> <strong>of</strong> Pakistan.<br />

Americanjournal<strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics, Vol. 61, No. I, pp 64-69<br />

Knight F.H, 1921. Risk. Uncertainty <strong>and</strong> Pr<strong>of</strong>it. New York: Houghton Mifflin <strong>and</strong> Co.<br />

Koukebene E.M, R. H. Hornbaker <strong>and</strong> BJ. Shetrick, 1996. Effects <strong>of</strong> Government Program Payments on<br />

Farm Portfolio <strong>Diversification</strong>. Review <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics, Vol. 18, No.2, PI'. 281-291<br />

Krishna R., 1963. Farm Supply Response in India-Pakistan: A <strong>Case</strong> Study <strong>of</strong> the Punjab Region. The<br />

Economic Journal. Vol. 73 No.291. pp. 477-487<br />

212


Kumar A., S.K Sharma, <strong>and</strong> Gn Vashist, 2002. Pr<strong>of</strong>itability, Risk <strong>and</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> in Mountain<br />

Agriculture: Some Policy Issues for Slow Growth <strong>Crops</strong>. Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics.<br />

Vol. 57, No.3, July-Sept 2002<br />

Kumar P <strong>and</strong> Mruthyunjaya, 2002. Long-Term Changes in Food Basket in India Paper Presented in An<br />

International Workshop on Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong> in South Asia, Jointly Organized by MOA,<br />

Bhutan, NCAP, IFPRI, Paro, Bhutan, 21-23 November 2002.<br />

Kumar P, Mruthyunjaya <strong>and</strong> P.S Birthal, 2003. Changing consumption pattern in South Asia. Paper<br />

Presented in the Intemational Workshop on Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Vertical Integration in<br />

South Asia organized by FICCI-ICRISAT-IFPRI on 50{; November in New Delhi.<br />

Kumar P., <strong>and</strong> S. Mittal, 2003. Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> in India: Analysis by State <strong>and</strong> Farm Size Group.<br />

Agricultural Situation in India. Vol. LX, No.5, August 2003, New Delhi.<br />

Kunreutber H <strong>and</strong> G.Wright, 1979. Safety First, Gambling <strong>and</strong> the Subsistence Farmer. In Roumasset J.A,<br />

J.M. Boussard <strong>and</strong> I. Singh (eds). Risk, Uncertainty <strong>and</strong> Agricultural Development. Southeast Asian<br />

Regional Centre for Graduate Study Research in Agriculture (SEARCA) <strong>and</strong> the Agricultural<br />

Development Council (ADC). Philippines <strong>and</strong> New Yark<br />

Kurosaki T. 2003. Specialisation <strong>and</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> in Agricultural Transformation: The <strong>Case</strong> <strong>of</strong> West<br />

Punjab, 1903-92. American Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 85, No.2, May 2003. pp. 372-86.<br />

----., 2005. Crop Choice, Farm Income <strong>and</strong> Political Relations in Myanmar. COE Discussion paper<br />

No. 80. Institute for Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo, Japan.<br />

Lau, LJ <strong>and</strong> P.A Yotopoulos, 1971. A Test for Relative Efficiency <strong>and</strong> Application to Indian Agriculture.<br />

The American Economic Review. Vol. 61, No.1 pp. 94-109<br />

-------.--------------, 1972. Pr<strong>of</strong>it Supply, <strong>and</strong> Factor Dem<strong>and</strong> Functions. American Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 54, pp. 11-18<br />

Lee T.H, 1975. Planrting Multiple Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> for Agricultural Development. The Philippine<br />

EconomicJournal, Vol. 14, No.l& 2, pp. 200-215.<br />

Levy H <strong>and</strong> M. Sarnat, 1972. Safety First- An Expected Utility Principle. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial <strong>and</strong><br />

Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 7, No.3, pp 1829-1834<br />

Lichtenberg E., 1989. L<strong>and</strong> Quality, Irrigation Development, <strong>and</strong> Cropping Patterns in tbe Northern High<br />

Plains. American Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 71, No. I pp. 187-194<br />

Maji C.C, D. Jha <strong>and</strong> L.S Venkataramanan, 1971. Dynamic Supply <strong>and</strong> Dem<strong>and</strong> Models for Better<br />

Estimations <strong>and</strong> Projections: An Econometric Study for Major Food grains in the Punjab Region.<br />

Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol 36, pp. 21-34<br />

M<strong>and</strong>ac A.M, J.H Narciso <strong>and</strong> J.C Flinn, 1990. Socia-Economic Constraints to Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

Intensification in Guimba, Neuva Ecija.IRRI v15n03, pp 147-155<br />

Markowitz H. 1959. Portfolio Selection: Efficient <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>of</strong> investment. Yale University Press,<br />

Yale<br />

Martin L.R., P.L Strickl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> EJ Partenheimer, 1965. implications <strong>of</strong> Alternative Cotton Acreage<br />

Allotment Levels. Journal <strong>of</strong>farm Economics. Vol 47, No.5, pp. 1203-1207<br />

213


McCalla A. F., 1997. From Subsistence Systems to Commercial Agriculture. The Need for a New<br />

Development Paradigm. American Journal <strong>of</strong> AgricultllTal Economics. Vol. 79, No.2 pp. 643-45<br />

McCalla A.F, <strong>and</strong> A. Valdes, 1999. <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> International Trade. In Peters G.H., <strong>and</strong> J V Braun;<br />

Food Security, <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Resource Management: Re-focusing the Role <strong>of</strong> Agriculture.<br />

Ashgate Publication, USA.<br />

Medellin M.A, LP. Apedaile <strong>and</strong> D. Pachico, 1994. Commercialization <strong>and</strong> Price Response <strong>of</strong> a Bean<br />

Growing Farming System in Colombia. Economic Development <strong>and</strong> Cultural Change. VoL42, No.4.<br />

pp.795-816<br />

Mehta R., 2005. Dynamics <strong>of</strong> Crop <strong>Diversification</strong>: A Quantitative Analysis. Commission for Agricultural<br />

Costs <strong>and</strong> Prices (CACP) Working Paper Series No. 1-2005. http://dacnet.nic.inlcacplcacpbook.html<br />

Mellor J, 1976. The New Economics <strong>of</strong> Growth. Itbaca, New York, Cornell University Press<br />

Minhas B.S. <strong>and</strong> A. Vaidhyanathan, 1965. Growth <strong>of</strong> Crop Output in India, 1951-54 to 1958-61, Analysis<br />

by Component Elements, Journal <strong>of</strong> Indian Society <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Statistics, Vol. 28 No.2, pp. 230-<br />

252.<br />

Minhas B. S., 1966. Rapporteur's Report on Measurement <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Growth, Indian Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Agricultural Economics, Vol 21, No.4, pp. 165-182.<br />

Minot N,M, T. Epprecht,T.T Anb <strong>and</strong> LQ Trung, 2006. Income <strong>Diversification</strong> in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>of</strong><br />

Vietnam. Research Repon, 145, IFPRI, Washington DC<br />

Mishra A.K <strong>and</strong> B.K Goodwin, 1997. Farm Income Variability <strong>and</strong> the Off-Farm Labour Supply.<br />

American Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural EconomiCS, Vol. 79, No.3, pp 880-887<br />

Mruthyunjaya <strong>and</strong> S. Chauban, 2003. Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> in Indian Agriculture: Silent Revolution<br />

Towards Agribusiness. Agricultural Situation in India. Vol. LX, No.5, August 2003, New Delhi.<br />

Mukhopadhyay S.K, 1976. Sources <strong>of</strong> Variation in Agricultural Productivity: A Cross section time-series<br />

study in India. The Macmillan Company <strong>of</strong> India Limited, Delhi<br />

Mullen J.D, C Escalante, G Hoogenboom, <strong>and</strong> Y. Yu, 2005. Determinants <strong>of</strong> Irrigation Farmers' Crop<br />

Choice <strong>and</strong> Acreage Allocation Decisions: Opportunity for Extension Service Delivery. Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Extension, Vol. 43, No.5<br />

Mythili G., 2006. Supply Response <strong>of</strong> Indian Farmers: Pre <strong>and</strong> Post Reforms. Working Paper 2006-009,<br />

IGIDR, Mumbai. http://www.igidr.ac.inlpd£lpublicationlWP-2006-009.pdf<br />

Naampoothiry M.M ,2003. Trends in Cropping Pattern vis-a-vis Price Trends. Agricultural Situation in<br />

India, August, Vol. 60, No.5, pp297-306.<br />

Nadkarni M. V., 1980. Market Surplus <strong>and</strong> Market Dependence. Allied Publishers, New Delhi, India.<br />

Nadkarni M.V., <strong>and</strong> K.H Vedini, 1996. Accelerating Commercialization <strong>of</strong> Agriculture: Dynamic<br />

Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Stagnation Peasants? Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekiy, Vol 31, No.26. pp.A-63 to A-<br />

73.<br />

Narain D., 1965. Impact <strong>of</strong> Price Movements on Areas under Selected <strong>Crops</strong> in India: 1900-1939.<br />

Cambridge University Press. New Delhi<br />

214


-----, 1976. Growth <strong>of</strong> Productivity in Indian Agriculture, Imlian JOIIT7IDI <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics.<br />

Vol. 32, No.1, pp. 1-44<br />

Narender I., G.M. Swamy <strong>and</strong> P.B. Parthasarathy, 1989. District-wise Measurement <strong>and</strong> Decomposition <strong>of</strong><br />

the Growth <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Output in Andhra <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Agricultural Situation in India, Vol. 44, No.1,<br />

pp.3-7.<br />

Nartea G.V <strong>and</strong> P J BaITy, 1994. Risk Efficiency <strong>and</strong> Costs Effects <strong>of</strong> Geographic <strong>Diversification</strong>. Review<br />

<strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 16, No.3. pp. 341-351<br />

Naru1a, S. <strong>and</strong> S. Vidyasagar, 1973. Methodology <strong>of</strong> Working Out Contribution <strong>of</strong> Area <strong>and</strong> Yield in<br />

Increasing Production, Agricultural Situation in India, Vol. 27, No.3, pp. 473-477.<br />

Nerlove M, 1958. The DynamiCS <strong>of</strong> Supply Estimation <strong>of</strong> Fanners' Response to Price. John Hopkins<br />

University Press, Baltimore.<br />

Ner10ve M, S. Vosti <strong>and</strong> W. Basel, 1996. Role <strong>of</strong> Farm-Level <strong>Diversification</strong> in the Adoption <strong>of</strong> Modern<br />

Technology in Brazil. Research Report No. 104. IFPRl, Washington DC.<br />

Norman D.W, <strong>and</strong> E.N. Castle, 1967. Geography <strong>and</strong> Agricultural Income: An Additional Hypothesis.<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Farm Economics, Vol.49, No.3. pp. 571-583<br />

Nowshirvani V.F 1971. L<strong>and</strong> Allocation under Uncertainty in Subsistence Agriculture. Oxford Economic<br />

Papers, New Series, Vol.23, No.3, Nov 1971, pp. 445-455<br />

Omarno S, 1998. Transport <strong>and</strong> Smallholder Cropping Choices: An Application to Siaya district, Kenya.<br />

American Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics, Vol. 80, pp 116-123.<br />

Ortiz S., 1979. The Effect <strong>of</strong> Risk Aversion Strategies on Subsistence <strong>and</strong> Cash Crop Decisions. In<br />

Roumasset 1.A, I. M Boussard <strong>and</strong> I. Singh (eds). Risk. Uncertainty <strong>and</strong> Agricultural Development.<br />

Southeast Asian Regional Centre for Graduate Study Research in Agriculture (SEARCA) <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Agricultural Development Council (ADC). Philippines <strong>and</strong> New York<br />

Pagoulatos A, S Marzin <strong>and</strong> D.L. Debartin, 1987. <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Farm Acreage Variation in Kentucky<br />

Counties. North Central Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 9, No.1 pp. 65-75<br />

P<strong>and</strong>ey V.K. <strong>and</strong> K.C Sharma, 1996. Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Self-Sufficiency in Food grains. Indian<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 51, No.4. pp 644-651.<br />

Parikh, A., 1966. Analysis <strong>of</strong> Growth Components <strong>and</strong> Methods <strong>of</strong> Contracting the Index Number <strong>of</strong><br />

Agricultural Production Under Constant Cropping Pattern, Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics.<br />

Vol. 21, No.3, pp. 41-47.<br />

Pingali, P.L, <strong>and</strong> M. Rosegrant, 1995. "Agricultural Commercialization <strong>and</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong>: Processes <strong>and</strong><br />

Policies". Food Policy. Vol 20, No 3, pp 171-185<br />

Pingali, P.L, 1997. From Subsistence to Commercial Production Systems: The Transformation <strong>of</strong> Asian<br />

Agriculture. American Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 79, No.2 pp. 628-634<br />

------------, 2004. Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong>: Opportunities <strong>and</strong> Constraints. FAO Rice Con/erence.<br />

Rome, Italy, 12-13 Feb 2004.<br />

215


Pingali, P.L, Y Khwaja, <strong>and</strong> M Meijer, 2005. Commercializing Small Farms: Reducing Transaction Costs.<br />

Working paper No. 04-05. Agricultural <strong>and</strong> Development Economics Division. Food <strong>and</strong> Agriculture<br />

Organization.<br />

Pope R.D., <strong>and</strong> R Prescott, 1980. <strong>Diversification</strong> in Relation to Farm Size <strong>and</strong> Other Socioeconomic<br />

Characteristics. American Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol 62, No.3, Aug 1980.<br />

Prabha C., 1971. District-wise Measurement <strong>of</strong> Decomposition <strong>of</strong> the Growth <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Output in the<br />

Punjab during Post-Independence Period, Indian Economic Review, Vol. 6, No.1, pp. 49-63.<br />

Pratt J.W, 1964. Risk Aversion in tbe Small in the Large. Econometrica Vol. 32. pp 122-136<br />

Quiroz J.A, <strong>and</strong> A. Valdes, 1995. Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Policy Reform. Food Policy. Vol 20,<br />

No 3, pp 245-255<br />

Rahman ML. <strong>and</strong> R.K. Talukder, 2001. Inter-linkages <strong>of</strong> Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong> in Bangladesh.<br />

MAP Focus Study Series No.9. Centre on Integrated Rural Development for Asia <strong>and</strong> the Pacific<br />

(CIRDAP), Dhaka.<br />

Raj K.N, A Sen <strong>and</strong> C.H.H Ran, 1988. Studies on Indian Agriculture: Dharm Narain. Oxford University<br />

Press, New Delhi<br />

Ramaswami B., S. Ravi <strong>and</strong> S.D Chopra, 2004. Risk Management. State <strong>of</strong> the Indian farmer. A<br />

Millennium Study, No. 22. Academic Foundation, New Delhi<br />

Ramaswami B., P S. Birthal <strong>and</strong> P. K. Joshi, 2005. Efficiency <strong>and</strong> Distribution in Contract Farming: The<br />

<strong>Case</strong> <strong>of</strong> Indian Poultry Growers. Discussion Paper 05-0J, February, 2005. lSI, Delhi<br />

Ranade, C.G., 1980. Impact <strong>of</strong> Cropping Pattern on Agricultural Production, Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural<br />

Economics, Vol. 35, No.2, pp. 85-92.<br />

Rao C.H.H, 2005. Agricultural growth, Farm Size <strong>and</strong> Rural Poverty Alleviation in India. Academic<br />

Foundation, New Delhi.<br />

Rao J.R., 2003. Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> in India: Policies, Programmes <strong>and</strong> Perspectives. AgricuJtural<br />

Situation in India. Vol. LX, No.5, August 2003, New Delhi.<br />

Rao P. P, P.S. Birthal, P.K. Joshi <strong>and</strong> D. Kar, 2004. Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong> in India <strong>and</strong> Role <strong>of</strong><br />

Urbanization. MITD Discussion Paper 77, IFPRJ, Washington D.C<br />

Rao S.K, 1971. Inter-regional Variations in Agricultural Growth, 1952-53 to 1964-65: A Tentative<br />

Analysis in Relation to Irrigation. Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, Vol. 6, July 3, pp 1333-1346.<br />

Reardon T., P Malton <strong>and</strong> C. Delgado, 1988. Coping with Household Level Food Insecurity in Drought<br />

Affected Areas <strong>of</strong> Burkina Faso. World Development, Vol. 16, No.9, pp 1065-1074<br />

Reardon T., C. Delgado <strong>and</strong> P Malton <strong>and</strong>, 1992. Detenninants <strong>and</strong> Effects <strong>of</strong> Income <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

amongst Farm Households in Burkina Faso. Journal <strong>of</strong> Development Studies, Vol. 28, pp 264-296.<br />

Rosenzweig M.<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> H.P Binswanger, 1993. Wealth, Weather Risk <strong>and</strong> the Composition <strong>and</strong> Probability<br />

<strong>of</strong> Agricultural investment. Economic Journal, Vol. 103, pp. 56-78.<br />

216


Roumasset 1.A, 1976. Rice <strong>and</strong> Risk: Decision-lIIIIling among Low-income Farmers. North Holl<strong>and</strong><br />

Publishing Company, New York<br />

Roy A.D, 1952. Safety First <strong>and</strong> the Holding <strong>of</strong> Assets. Econometrica. Vol. 20, No.3, pp. 431-449<br />

Rudra A., 1982. Indian Agricultural Economics: Myths <strong>and</strong> Realities. Allied Publishers private limited,<br />

New Delhi<br />

Saleth R.M, 1996. <strong>Diversification</strong> as a Strategy for Small Farm Development: Some Evidence from Tamil<br />

Nadu. NeAP Workshop Proceedings I, New Delhi, March 1996<br />

Samuelson P. 1967. A General Pro<strong>of</strong> that DiveT1iification Pays. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Quantitative<br />

Analaysis. Vol. 2, No.1, pp. 1-13.<br />

Sarjent MJ. 1973. Economics in Horticulture. English Language Book Society <strong>and</strong> MacMillan Press.<br />

Sarma, P.V. <strong>and</strong> S. Subrahmanyam, 1984. A Note on tbe Decomposition <strong>of</strong> the Growth Rate <strong>of</strong> Aggregate<br />

Crop Output,Agricultural Situation in India, Vol. 39, No.9, pp. 691-694.<br />

Sawant. S, 1978. Supply Behaviour in Agriculture: An Econometric Analysis. Himalaya Publishing House,<br />

Bombay<br />

Schurle B.W., <strong>and</strong> B.L Erven, 1979. The Trade-<strong>of</strong>f Between Return <strong>and</strong> Risk in Farm Enterprise Choice.<br />

North Central Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. I, No.1, pp 15-21<br />

Shackle GL.S., 1949. Etpectation in Economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, Engl<strong>and</strong><br />

--------, 1958. lime in Economics. Amsterdam, North Holl<strong>and</strong> Publishing Company.<br />

-----------, 1970. Expectation, Enterprise <strong>and</strong> Pr<strong>of</strong>it: The Theory <strong>of</strong> the Firm. George Allen <strong>and</strong><br />

Unwin Ltd, London.<br />

Shahabuddin Q., S. Mestelman <strong>and</strong> D. Feeny, 1986. Peasant Behaviour Towards Risk <strong>and</strong> Socia-Economic<br />

<strong>and</strong> Structural Characteristics <strong>of</strong> Farm Households in Bangladesh. Orford Economic Papers. Vol. 38,<br />

No. l,pp. 122-130<br />

Shankar U, <strong>and</strong> G. Mythili, 1991. Uncertainty <strong>and</strong> Farm Production Decisions. Himalaya Publishing<br />

House, Bombay<br />

Sharma H.R., V Kumar, <strong>and</strong> A.K Tripathi, 2003. <strong>Horticultural</strong> in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>: Emerging Threats<br />

from Globalization, Technological <strong>and</strong> Climatic Changes. Man <strong>and</strong> Development. Vol. 25, No.1, pp.<br />

21-34.<br />

Sharma H.R., 2005. Agricultural Development <strong>and</strong> Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>:<br />

Underst<strong>and</strong>ing the Patterns, Processes, Detenninants <strong>and</strong> Lessons. Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural<br />

&onomics. Vol.60, No.1, pp.71-93.<br />

Sharma, J.L. <strong>and</strong> J. Singh, 1986. Growth <strong>of</strong> Crop Output in Punjab, Agricultural Situation in India, Vol. 41,<br />

No.7, pp. 551-553.<br />

Sharma, K.L., 1977. Measurement <strong>of</strong> the Effects <strong>of</strong> Area, Yield <strong>and</strong> Prices in the Increase <strong>of</strong> Value <strong>of</strong> Crop<br />

Output in India, Agricultural Situation in India, Vol. 32, No.6, pp. 349-351.<br />

217


Shetty, S.A., 1970. Agricultural Production Trends <strong>and</strong> Components, Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural<br />

Economics, VoL 25, No.2, pp. 28-48.<br />

Sidhu H.S, 2002. Crisis in agrarian economy in Punjab: Some Urgent Steps. Economic <strong>and</strong> Political<br />

Weekly, July, pp. 3132-3138<br />

Sidhu SOS <strong>and</strong> C A. Baanante, 1981. Estimating Farm-Level Input Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Wheat Supply in the Indian<br />

Punjab using a Translog Pr<strong>of</strong>it Function. American Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 63, No.2,<br />

pp.237-246<br />

Siju, T. <strong>and</strong> S. Kombairaju, 2001. Rice Production in Tamil Nadu: A Trend <strong>and</strong> Decomposition Analysis,<br />

Agricultural Situation in India, Vol. 58, No.4, pp. 143-145.<br />

Sikka, B.K. <strong>and</strong> COS. Vaidya, 1985. Growth Rates <strong>and</strong> Cropping Pattern Changes in Agriculture in<br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Agricultural Situation in India, VoL 39, No. II, pp. 843-846.<br />

Singh D.V. 1990. Production <strong>and</strong> Marketing <strong>of</strong> Off-season Vegetables. Mittai Publications, New Delhi.<br />

------------, 1981. A Component Analysis <strong>and</strong> Value Productivity Growth <strong>of</strong> bnportant <strong>Crops</strong> in<br />

<strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>, Agricultural Situation in India, VoL 36, No.6, pp. 479-484<br />

Singh H.P., P. Nath, O.P. Dulla, <strong>and</strong> M. Sudha, 2004. Horticulture Development. VoL II, State <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Indian Fanner: A Millennium Study. Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Cooperation, Ministry <strong>of</strong><br />

Agriculture, Government <strong>of</strong>India. New Delhi.<br />

Singh H. <strong>and</strong> J. P Pawar, 1998. Fruit Growing in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>. Farmer's Bulletin No. I. Directorate<br />

<strong>of</strong> Horticulture. Shimla<br />

Singh J <strong>and</strong> RS Sidhu, 2004. Factors in Declining Crop <strong>Diversification</strong>: <strong>Case</strong> <strong>of</strong> Punjab. Economic <strong>and</strong><br />

Polictical Weekly. December 2004. pp. 56-7·56 \0<br />

Singh R. <strong>and</strong> B.K Sikka, 1992. Marketing <strong>of</strong> High Value Perishable <strong>Crops</strong> in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>. Agro<br />

Economic Research Centre, Shimla. HP<br />

Singh R., P Singh, <strong>and</strong> S.P Saraswat, 2004. Building up <strong>of</strong> an Efficient Marketing System to Obviate Need<br />

for a Large Scale State Intervention in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>. Agro Economic Research Centre, Shimla.<br />

HP<br />

Singh R., S.P Saraswat <strong>and</strong> P. Singh, 2004. Agricultural Policy Matrix in <strong>Himachal</strong> <strong>Pradesh</strong>: A Policy<br />

Matrix in a Federal System. Agro &onomic Research Centre, Shimla. HP<br />

Singh R. <strong>and</strong> C.S Vaidya, 2005. Production Marketing Storage <strong>and</strong> Transportation Losses in Selected<br />

Vegetables in Shimla <strong>and</strong> Solan Districts. Agro Economic Research Centre, Shiml .. HP<br />

Singh R.P, 1996. Farm Level <strong>Diversification</strong> in Dry l<strong>and</strong> Regions <strong>of</strong> India. In Haque T. (eds), 1996. Small<br />

Farm <strong>Diversification</strong>: Problems <strong>and</strong> Prospects, NCAP Workshop Proceedings I, New Delhi, March<br />

1996<br />

Suleiman A., 2004. Smallholder Supply Response <strong>and</strong> Gender in Ethiopia: A Pr<strong>of</strong>it Function Analysis.<br />

Sheffield &onomic Research Paper Series. No. 2004007. UK<br />

218


Sumner D.A, 2004. What to Pull? What to Plant? Economic Basics.<br />

http://aic.ucdavis.edulevents/pom 04/%5B2%5D%20Sumner.pdf<br />

Suresh A. <strong>and</strong> T.R.K Reddy, 2006. Resource-use Efficiency <strong>of</strong> Paddy Cultivation in Peechi Comm<strong>and</strong> Area<br />

<strong>of</strong> Thrissur district <strong>of</strong> Kerala: An Economic Analysis. Agricultural Economics Research Review. Vol.<br />

19, January-June 2006. pp 159-171<br />

Timmer C.P, 1997. Farmers <strong>and</strong> Markets: The Political Economy <strong>of</strong> New Paradigms. American Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Agricultural Economics. Vol. 79 May 1997. pp.621-{;27.<br />

Tweeten L, 1989. Agricultural Policy Analysis Tools for Economic Development. west View Press,<br />

Boulder, USA.<br />

Umesh K.B <strong>and</strong> S. Bisalliah, 1991. Efficiency <strong>of</strong> Groupdnut Production in Karnataka: Frontier Pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

Function Approach. Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol 49, No.1. pp. 20-33<br />

Van L.W.T <strong>and</strong> L.H Keller, 2006. Farmers' Decision Making: Perceptions <strong>of</strong> the importance, Uncertainty,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Controllability <strong>of</strong> Selected Factors. Agribusiness. Vol 7, No 6, pp. 523-525<br />

Venkataramanan, L.S <strong>and</strong> M. PrahJadachar, 1980. Growth Rates <strong>and</strong> Cropping Pattern Changes in<br />

Agriculture in Six States: 1950 to 1975, Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics, Vol. 35, No.2, pp.<br />

71-84.<br />

Verma B.N <strong>and</strong> R.R Mishra, 1997. Crop <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Related Issues on Small Farms in North Bihar.<br />

Agricultural Situation in India, July 1997, pp 181-197<br />

Vidyasagar, 1977. A Component Analysis <strong>of</strong> the Growth <strong>of</strong> Productivity <strong>and</strong> Production in Rajasthan:<br />

1956-{;1 to 1969-74, Indian Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics, Vol.32, No.1 pp. 108-1\9.<br />

---------, 1980. Decomposition <strong>of</strong> Growth Trends <strong>and</strong> Certain Related Issues, Indian Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Agricultural Economics, Vol. 35, No.2, pp. 42-59.<br />

Vyas, V.S., 1996. "<strong>Diversification</strong> in Agriculture: Concept, Rationale <strong>and</strong> Approaches", Indian Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Agricultural Economics Vol. 51, No.4. pp. 636-643.<br />

Walker T.S <strong>and</strong> J.G Ryan, 1990. Vii/age <strong>and</strong> Household Economies in India's Semi-arid Tropics.<br />

Baltimore, John Hopkins University Press.<br />

Webster J.P.G, <strong>and</strong> J.O.S Kennedy, 1975. Measuring Farmers' Trade-Offs Between Expected Income <strong>and</strong><br />

Focus-Loss Income. American Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural &onomics. Vol. 57, No. I pp.97-105<br />

Weimar M.R. <strong>and</strong> A Hallam, 1988. Risk, <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> Vegetables as an Alternative Crop for<br />

Midwestern Agriculture. North Central Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 10. No. I. pp. 75-89<br />

White T., <strong>and</strong> G. Irwin, 1972. Farm Size <strong>and</strong> Specialisation. In Ball G., <strong>and</strong> E Heady (Ed.). Size. Structure<br />

<strong>and</strong> future <strong>of</strong> farmers. Ames lA, Iowa State University Press<br />

Wik M. 1996. Individual Decision Making under Risk: Deficiencies <strong>of</strong> <strong>and</strong> Alternatives to Expected Utility<br />

Theory. NLH Agricultural University <strong>of</strong> Norway Discussion Paper #D-23/1996.<br />

219


Williams D.B, 1951. Price Expectations <strong>and</strong> Reactioos to Uncertainty by Farmers in Dlinois. Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Farm Economics, Vol. 33, No. I, pp20-39<br />

World Bank, 1988. <strong>Diversification</strong> in Rural Asia. Working paper Series No. \18, Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural<br />

Development Department, The World Bank, Washington DC, USA.<br />

------, 1990. Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong> Policies <strong>and</strong> Issues from East Asian Experiences. Policy<br />

<strong>and</strong> Research Series n. Agricultural <strong>and</strong> Rural Development Department, World Bank, Washington,<br />

D.C., U.S.A.<br />

Wu JJ, 1999. Crop Insurance, Acreage Decisions, <strong>and</strong> Non-Point Source Pollution. American Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Agricultural Economics. Vol. 81, No.2 pp. 305-320<br />

Yilma T, 2005. Modelling Farm Irrigation Decisions uoder Rainfall Risk in the White-Volta Basin <strong>of</strong><br />

Ghana: A Tool for Policy Analysis at the Farm-Household Level. http://www.glowavoltadelpublicationsiprintedlthesis<br />

yilma.pdf<br />

Yokoyama S, 1995. Agricultural <strong>Diversification</strong> aod institutional Change: A <strong>Case</strong> Study <strong>of</strong> Tenancy<br />

Contract in Indonesia. The Developing Economies. Vol. 3, No.4. pp.374-396<br />

Young D.L, 1979. Risk Preferences <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Producers: Their Use in Extension <strong>and</strong> Research.<br />

American Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics. Vol. 61, No.5. pp 1063-1070<br />

Yotopoulos P.A, L.J Lau, <strong>and</strong> W.L Lin, 1976. Microeconomic Output Supply <strong>and</strong> Factor Dem<strong>and</strong><br />

Functions in the Agriculture <strong>of</strong> the Province <strong>of</strong> Taiwan. American Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics.<br />

Vol. 58, No.2 pp. 333-340<br />

Zellner A., 1962. An Efficient Method <strong>of</strong> Estimating Seemingly Unrelated Regression <strong>and</strong> Tests for<br />

Aggregation Bias. Journal <strong>of</strong> the American Statistical Association. Vol. 57, No. 298. pp 348-368<br />

Zimmerer K.S, 1991. Labour Shortages <strong>and</strong> Crop Diversities in the Southern Peruvian Sierra.<br />

Geographical Review. Vol. 81, No.4. pp414-432<br />

220

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!