07.03.2014 Views

Institutional finance for agriculture: Analysis at macro and micro levels

Institutional finance for agriculture: Analysis at macro and micro levels

Institutional finance for agriculture: Analysis at macro and micro levels

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

INSTITUTIONAL FINANCE FOR<br />

AGRICULTURE<br />

A:\;ALYSIS AT \L\CRO A.:\;D \lIeRO LE\'ELS<br />

A thesi.r submitted to the Ullil'ersit)' ol,\l)so,.e, ,\1)".rore,./o,. the award oltbe f)(~n'C<br />

olDodor o(Pbi/osop~)' ill E'ollolJli,:r<br />

l" nder rhe.: ~upc.:n·iSl()n of<br />

Prof. D Rajasekhar<br />

Institute <strong>for</strong> Social aM Economic Change, Bangalore<br />

/<br />

/<br />

. ,/<br />

\I'r!I::III~<br />

~~--- --- ....<br />

\<br />

\. "<br />

t • I<br />

c-,: 1_'-<br />

/.


'7Tiis is to certify th<strong>at</strong> this thesis entitfeef ''<strong>Institutional</strong> 'Finance Jar )f.griculture:<br />

)f.nalysis <strong>at</strong> 9;(acro <strong>and</strong> 9;(icro revels" is a 60naJiefe research war/( carn'ref out 6)'<br />

§'agan (]3lhari Sahu inefepenefentfy unefer my Bu!efance anef supervIsIon.<br />

I also certify th<strong>at</strong> this has not 6een previousfy su6mitteef Jar the award' oj any efegree<br />

or efipfoma or associ<strong>at</strong>eship to any other university or instItution.<br />

lD<strong>at</strong>e: )f.pn[5, 2004<br />

J) . R~


I here6y decCare tfi<strong>at</strong> tfie thesis entided "InstitutiolUl{ q:inance <strong>for</strong> }fgricufture:<br />

}flUlfysis <strong>at</strong> Macro <strong>at</strong>ufMicro fevefs" is a resu{t of research. wor/(camcd-out 6} me ilt<br />

the Institute <strong>for</strong> Socia{ <strong>and</strong> 'Economic Cfiange, under tfie gUIdance of IDr, .0<br />

(RiLjaseRfiar, (Professor, ([Jecentra{is<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong>(Velidopment Vnit, IS'EC, :13allgu{ore,<br />

I furtfier decCare tfi<strong>at</strong> it fias not Geen prf'l'iousfy su6mltted eitfier in part orfu{{ to<br />

tliis or any otfier university <strong>for</strong> any degree, ([Jue acl00wledjJements fiave 6eetz mad,'<br />

wlienever any tliing fias Geen 60rrowed or cited from otlier sources,<br />

(D<strong>at</strong>e: }fpri{ 5, 2004<br />

.,' - -<br />

.:'!.<br />

(j'agan IBiiiari .saiiu


GLOSSARY<br />

CONTENTS<br />

a<br />

INTRODUCTION 1<br />

St<strong>at</strong>ement of the Problem 1<br />

Conceptual Framework 7<br />

Objectives of the Study 11<br />

Scope of the Study 12<br />

Chapter Scheme 14<br />

POLICIES, PROGRESS AND PROBLEMS IN AGRICULTURAL<br />

CREDIT: THEORETICAL ISSUES 17<br />

Introduction 17<br />

Phases of Banking Policies 18<br />

Movement of Directed Credit in India 31<br />

Subsidised Interest R<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> Its Impact on Agricultural Credit Flow 35<br />

Borrowing Costs <strong>and</strong> Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> Credit 41<br />

Concluding Remarks 44<br />

CREDIT FLOW TO AGRICULTURE: TRENDS AND CONTRIBUTING<br />

FACTORS AT ALL-INDIA LEVEL 49<br />

Introduction 49<br />

Credit Flow to Agriculture 52<br />

Distribution P<strong>at</strong>tern of Agricultural Credit of SCBs 57<br />

Achievement of SCBs in Agricultural Finance 62<br />

Credit Subsidy in Indian Agriculture 65<br />

Number of Rural Bank Branches <strong>and</strong> Agricultural Credit 71<br />

Determinants of Supply of Agricultural Credit 72<br />

Conclusions 77<br />

INSTITUTIONAL CREDIT TO AGRICULTURE: STATE AND<br />

DISTRICT LEVEL ANALYSIS 80<br />

Introduction 80<br />

R<strong>at</strong>ionale of St<strong>at</strong>e Selection <strong>and</strong> D<strong>at</strong>abase 81<br />

St<strong>at</strong>e-wise Flow of Agricultural Credit 83<br />

Distribution P<strong>at</strong>tern of Agricultural Credit 90<br />

Determinants of Credit Flow to Agriculture <strong>at</strong> the St<strong>at</strong>e Level 97


Credit Flow to Agriculture in Orissa<br />

District Level <strong>Analysis</strong> on Agricultural Credit Flow<br />

Conclusions<br />

105<br />

110<br />

117<br />

HOW DID MACRO POLICY OPERATE AT THE MICRO LEVEL? AN<br />

ANALYSIS OF CREDIT FLOW IN THE SELECTED BANK BRANCHES<br />

IN KALAHANDI DISTRICT, ORISSA 120<br />

Introduction 120<br />

D<strong>at</strong>abase 122<br />

Priority Sector Lending 132<br />

Agricultural Lending 136<br />

Security Based Lending 141<br />

Inter-Regional Differences in Priority Sector Lending <strong>and</strong> Deposits 145<br />

Conclusions 150<br />

VARIATIONS IN THE FLOW OF CREDIT TO FARM HOUSEHOLDS:<br />

i53<br />

Introduction<br />

N<strong>at</strong>ure of Credit Dem<strong>and</strong> of Different C<strong>at</strong>egories of Farmers<br />

Sources of D<strong>at</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Econometric Methodology<br />

Emerging P<strong>at</strong>terns in Rural Credit Market<br />

Factors Affecting Access to Formal Credit<br />

Determinants of Supply of Agricultural Credit<br />

Conclusions<br />

153<br />

154<br />

156<br />

160<br />

164<br />

170<br />

178<br />

CREDIT DELIVERY SYSTEM, CREDIT-GAP AND COPING<br />

STRATEGY OF AGRICULTURAL BORROWERS<br />

Introduction<br />

Credit Delivery System<br />

Borrowing Costs <strong>for</strong> Agricultural Credit<br />

The Credit-Gap ICG)<br />

The Coping Str<strong>at</strong>egies of Farmer Borrowers<br />

Conclusions<br />

SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS<br />

REFERENCES<br />

181<br />

181<br />

182<br />

188<br />

191<br />

196<br />

208<br />

210<br />

231


Figure 1.1: Factors th<strong>at</strong> Determine the Accessibility of Credit.. 1:<br />

Table 2.1: Distribution of Total Debt of Rural Households by Different Sources ................ 2\:<br />

Table 2.2: Lending Targets <strong>for</strong> Agriculture Sector.. . ................. 2"<br />

Box 2.1: Recommend<strong>at</strong>ions of the Gupta CommIttee ..<br />

Figure 2.1: R<strong>at</strong>ioning Behaviour of the Lender .........<br />

Figure 2.2: Borrowing Costs <strong>and</strong> Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> Credit<br />

, ............................................. ~7<br />

.. ..... ~o<br />

................................... ·14<br />

Table 3.1: Annual Average Growth R<strong>at</strong>es of Credit (~o) by SClls to Different Sc·ctors.. .54<br />

Table 3.2: Bank Group-wise Share of Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit of SCBs to Agriculture from<br />

Net Bank Credit........................................... ................ . ........................ 55<br />

Table 3.3: Distribution (%) of Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit <strong>for</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Allied Activities<br />

(Short <strong>and</strong> Long-Term) by Different Types of Lending Institutions. . ........ 56<br />

Table 3.4: Annual Average Growth R<strong>at</strong>es (%) of Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit to Agriculture. .. ..... 5;<br />

Table 3.5: Distribution of Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit to the Total Net Bank Credit by SClls (eo)<br />

by Sectors <strong>and</strong> Credit Limits .................. 5R<br />

Table 3.6: Distribution of Loan Accounts by seBs ('Yo) by Sectors <strong>and</strong> Credit Limits. .59<br />

Table 3.7: Distribution of Agricultural Credit by seBs ('Yo) by the Type of Lending R<strong>at</strong>es<br />

<strong>and</strong> Credit Limits ........................................................... ,........................... 61<br />

Table 3.8: Credit Limit-wise Annual Average Growth R<strong>at</strong>es of Loan Accounts ... . ............ 6~<br />

Table 3.9: Proportion of Credit Advanced to Agriculture from Net Bank Credit of SCBs<br />

(Including RRBs) ............................................... ............ . ...... 63<br />

Table 3.10: Distribution (%) of Direct Finance to Farmers by SCBs (Short <strong>and</strong> Long-Term<br />

Loans) by Size-Classes of L<strong>and</strong>holding............................... ..64<br />

Table 3.11: Distribution of Disbursement Loan Accounts on Direct Finance to Farmers by<br />

SCBs (Short-Term <strong>and</strong> Long-Term Loans)...................... . . .. .. ....... .65<br />

Table 3.12: Estim<strong>at</strong>ed Lending Costs Per Rs.l00 Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Loan. . ....... .... 67<br />

Table 3.13: Cost of Lending to Agricultural Sector rer Rs.l00 Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit of Clls<br />

Including RRBs .......... .......... .................... .....<br />

Table 3.14: Cost, Interest Income <strong>and</strong> Credit Subsidy to Agricultural Sector .. ...... 70<br />

Table 3.15: Region-Wise Growth R<strong>at</strong>e of Rural Bank Branches.... .. ............ .<br />

-,<br />

. .... " ...... ". i_<br />

Table 3.16: Description, Expected Sign <strong>and</strong> Coefficient of Variables Used in the Equ<strong>at</strong>ion ... 75<br />

. 6R<br />

Table 4.1: St<strong>at</strong>e-wise Annual Average Growth R<strong>at</strong>es (%) of Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit by SCBs ..... 84<br />

Table 4.2: St<strong>at</strong>e-wise Agricultural Sector Lending (~o) to Total Credit <strong>and</strong> Total Deposit.<br />

Table 4.3: St<strong>at</strong>e-wise <strong>and</strong> Size Class-wise Access to Direct Finance by the Farmers.<br />

Table 4.4: St<strong>at</strong>e-wise <strong>and</strong> Size Class-wise Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit (Direct Finance to Farme,,)<br />

Per Loan Account..... . ....... 9-1<br />

T"ble 4.5: St<strong>at</strong>e-wise <strong>and</strong> Size Class-wise Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit Per Hectare of Oper<strong>at</strong>i\'n,,1<br />

~ing ....... _........... . ... %<br />

Table 4.6: Estim<strong>at</strong>ion Result of Sargan's Criterion.... 101<br />

Table 4.7: Description, hpected Sign. <strong>and</strong> Coefficient of Variables in the Log-line,,,<br />

l\1odcl[Dependent Variable = CGA].. ... .......... 102<br />

. k7<br />

'1:\


Table 4.8: St<strong>at</strong>e Specific Intercepts of Fixed Effect Model.. I P .<br />

Table 4.9: Share of Agricultural Credit ('O) from Total Bank Credit bv Each Grnul' of<br />

Bank................................ .......................<br />

Table 4.10: Broad Sector-wise Distribution of Target <strong>and</strong> Achievements undl'f Annual<br />

Credit Plan of seBs (including RRB) ......<br />

Table 4.11: Some Selected Indic<strong>at</strong>ors of Sp<strong>at</strong>ial Distribution of Development. 111<br />

Table 4.12: Type of District-wise Share (%) of Agricultural Credit Given bv SeRs.. . ...... 111<br />

Table 4.13: District-wise Agricultural Sector Lending ('O) to Total Bank Credit <strong>and</strong><br />

Deposits .................................................................................. . ...... 11.1<br />

Table 4.14. Type of District-wise Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit Per Hectare of Gross Cropped Mea. 114<br />

Table 4.15: Description, Expected Sign, <strong>and</strong> Coefficient of Variables in the Log-Linear<br />

Model [Dependent variable = CGA] .................................... . ............... 116<br />

Table 4.16: District Specific Intercepts of Fixed Effect Model ............. .<br />

Ilt.<br />

He<br />

.. 116<br />

Table 5.1: Size Class-wise Number <strong>and</strong> Area under Oper<strong>at</strong>ional Holdings ..<br />

.124<br />

Table 5.2: Area under Irrig<strong>at</strong>ion, Fertiliser Consumption <strong>and</strong> Area under HYV IJ1<br />

Kalah<strong>and</strong>i District <strong>and</strong> Orissa .................................................... .<br />

Table 5.3: Socia-Economic Fe<strong>at</strong>ures of Kalah<strong>and</strong>i District ............................. .<br />

TE!b!e 5.4: Criteria to ~fine Advanced <strong>and</strong> Back ..·.. ard Blocks ..............<br />

Table 5.5: Sector-wise Flow of Bank Credit ................................................ .<br />

".. 12h<br />

. ...... 127<br />

'0,<br />

.............. 1.11<br />

............. 132<br />

Table 5.6: Purpose-wise Distribution of Agricultural Credit from 1996-97 to 2000·01 ........... 137<br />

Table 5.7: Sector-wise Recovery of Loan Amount to Dem<strong>and</strong> ...... .<br />

. .......... l3B<br />

Table 5.8: Interest Income on Advance ........................................ .. . ...... 1-10<br />

Table 5.9: Distribution of Agricultural Credit by Type of Security .......... .<br />

..I·B<br />

Table 5.10: Proportion of Priority Sector Lending to Total Credit <strong>and</strong> Total Deposits ........... 146<br />

Table 5.11: Proportion of Lending to Agriculture from Total Credit <strong>and</strong> Total Deposits ..... 147<br />

Graph 1: PSCBD <strong>and</strong> PSCBC in the Sample Bank Branches of jaip<strong>at</strong>na <strong>and</strong> Narla Block ..... 141'<br />

Graph 2: AGLCBD <strong>and</strong> AGLCBC in the Sample Bank Branches of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na <strong>and</strong> Narl.<br />

Block............................................................................. .150<br />

Table 6.1: Distribution of Borrowers by Farm Size (2001-02) ............. . ..161<br />

Table 6.2: Distribution of Loan by Farm Size in the Year 2001-02....... . ............. 162<br />

Table 6.3: L<strong>and</strong>holding-wise Number of Times Crop Loans (Kharif) Obtained bv<br />

Farmers <strong>for</strong> the Period 1999 - 2000 to 2001· 2002...... .16:1<br />

Table 6.4: Supply of Credit (Crop Loan) Per Hectare of Gross Cropped Area.<br />

Table 6.5: Definition, Measurement. Descriptive St<strong>at</strong>istics, <strong>and</strong> Expected Sign of<br />

Variables Used in the Prohit Equ<strong>at</strong>ion ............ . .............. 166<br />

Table 6.6: Access to Formal Credit: Probit Results ... 107<br />

Table 6.7: Definition, Measurement, Descriptive St<strong>at</strong>istics <strong>and</strong> Expected Sign of Variables<br />

used in the OLS Equ<strong>at</strong>ion...... J 7"<br />

Table 6.8: Determinants of <strong>for</strong>mal Credit: Selectivitv Correctl'd 01.5 Rl'sult.<br />

Table 6.9: Determinants of Formal Credit: Tobit Results ....<br />

Ih-l<br />

17S<br />

177


Table 7.1: Problems Faced by the Farmer Borrowers in Obtitining Loans<br />

Table 7.2: Size Class of L<strong>and</strong>holding-v.:ise Frequency Distribution of Problems Fd({'d b\'<br />

the Farmer Borrowers.......................... 1~S<br />

Table 7.3: Time Spent to get the Loan Sanctioned 187<br />

Table 7.4: Shortage of Amount Sanctioned to Amount Dem<strong>and</strong>ed.. 18~<br />

Table 7.5: Cost of Borrowing (Short-Term) from the Financial Institutions III till' Stud\,<br />

Area.................................................................... .. .............. 190<br />

Table 7.6: Cost of Borrowing of <strong>Institutional</strong> Credit by Farm Households According to<br />

the Size of Loan in the Study Area....................... . ....... 191<br />

Table 7.7: Extent of Dependency on Credit Per Acre of Gross Cropped Area (2001-02) ....... 192<br />

Table 7.8: L<strong>and</strong>holding-wise Credit-Gap....................... .. ....... .. . ... 195<br />

Table 7.9: Self-<strong>finance</strong> Capacity of Farmers Per Acre of Gross Cropped Area .. . ........ 196<br />

Table 7.10: Distribution of Borrowers by Number of Sources of Borrowing .................. . .. 197<br />

Table 7.11: The Predetermined Exchange R<strong>at</strong>e of Paddy in Interlocked Credit Market . 20~<br />

Table 7.12. Regions & L<strong>and</strong>holding-Wise Estim<strong>at</strong>ed Income Loss Per Bag of Selling<br />

Paddy due to Interlocked Credit Market in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i District, Orissa (2001-<br />

02) ...................................................................................... . .................... 205<br />

T?b!e 7,13: Farm Size <strong>and</strong> Coll<strong>at</strong>eral-wise Percentage of Lean Contracts <strong>and</strong> PErcEntag€<br />

of Loan (amount) Borrowed ............................................................. ................... . 207<br />

1B4


ABC<br />

ACRC<br />

AR<br />

ARC<br />

ATC<br />

Alls<br />

BC<br />

CBs<br />

CDR<br />

CFS<br />

CG<br />

Cl<br />

CRAFICARD<br />

CRR<br />

CRS<br />

CS<br />

DAP<br />

FFIs<br />

FRBS<br />

HYV<br />

IC<br />

IMR<br />

LAMPs<br />

LBO<br />

LDB<br />

LT<br />

MSP<br />

MVP<br />

NABARD<br />

NDC<br />

NDP<br />

OLS<br />

OPS<br />

PACSs<br />

PLCP<br />

PLR<br />

RBI<br />

RFIs<br />

RFMs<br />

RRB<br />

SAPs<br />

SBF<br />

SC/Sl<br />

SCBs<br />

SlR<br />

SSI<br />

ST<br />

TC<br />

TJ.<br />

TPS<br />

GLOSSARY<br />

Average Borrowing Cost<br />

Agricultural Credit Review Committee<br />

Average Revenue<br />

Agricultural Re<strong>finance</strong> Corpor<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

Average Transaction Cost<br />

Agricultural Term loans<br />

Borrowing cost<br />

Commercial Banks<br />

Credit Deposit R<strong>at</strong>io<br />

Committee on Financial System<br />

Credit-Gap<br />

Credit limit<br />

Committee to Review Arrangements <strong>for</strong> <strong>Institutional</strong> Credit <strong>for</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong><br />

Rural Development<br />

Cash Reserve Ra tio<br />

Constant Return to Scale<br />

Credit Subsidy<br />

Di-Ammonium Phosph<strong>at</strong>e<br />

Formal Financial Institutions<br />

Formal Rural Banking System<br />

High Yielding Varieties<br />

In<strong>for</strong>mal Credit<br />

Inverse Mills R<strong>at</strong>io<br />

Large Area Multi Purpose Societies<br />

Lead Bank Office<br />

L<strong>and</strong> Development Bank<br />

Long-Term<br />

Minimum Support Price<br />

Marginal Value Product<br />

N<strong>at</strong>ional Bank <strong>for</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural Development<br />

No Dues Certific<strong>at</strong>e<br />

Net Domestic Product<br />

Ordinary Least Squares<br />

Other Priority Sector<br />

Primary Agricultural Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive Societies<br />

Potential Linked Credit Plan<br />

Prime Lending R<strong>at</strong>e<br />

Reserve Bank of India<br />

Rural Financial Institutions<br />

Rural Financial Markets<br />

Regional Rural Bank<br />

Service Area Plans<br />

Small Business Firm<br />

Scheduled Caste <strong>and</strong> Scheduled Tribe<br />

Scheduled Commercial Banks<br />

St<strong>at</strong>utory Liquidity R<strong>at</strong>io<br />

Small Scale Industries<br />

Short-Term<br />

Transaction Cost<br />

Term-Loan<br />

Total Priority Sector


(Dun'llg my post graau<strong>at</strong>ioll aays, I usea to pOllacr tli<strong>at</strong> aoillg a aoetor<strong>at</strong>e was not a smarr<br />

job, ana was a aream <strong>for</strong> me. Toaay, my aream nas m<strong>at</strong>ena[uea 1I'itn tnc co-oper<strong>at</strong>lOli <strong>and</strong>'<br />

ne[p, a gre<strong>at</strong> aea{ of tnougnt ana ef<strong>for</strong>ts of many peopfe III many '!'ays. It is neltfier<br />

possibfe nor suffident to acli.JlOwfeage tfiem in tfiis fomw{ "Wllller witfi a fcw woras.<br />

'First alla <strong>for</strong>emost, I remaill aeepfy Illaebtea to my supervisor q'rof rD. '1(aFlSCliJiar unacr<br />

wnose abfe guiJallce tfiis war/( fias beell camea out. J{is fie[pfu{ cntlcism, suggestions,<br />

meticu{ous reaefillg ana eaiting, constant encouragement, ana avera{[ morae support maac It<br />

possl6fe <strong>for</strong> me to compfete tfie tfiesis alia to see tfie figlit of tfie aay, I a1ll ever gr<strong>at</strong>ifll{ to<br />

filln.<br />

)'ls a researcfi scfiora,., I fearnt a wt from rDr. S. :Maafieswllrun, on a number of eCOllOlme<br />

issues tfirougfi aisCUSSIOns, in genera(, ana on m<strong>at</strong>ters refuting to tfie app(ze<strong>at</strong>ion of<br />

quantit<strong>at</strong>ive tecliniques, in particufur. I fOlzafy cfierisfi alla va{ue my associ<strong>at</strong>ion witfi film,<br />

I wouUf Ms to e:;;press my sillcere tlian/(} to !Frof 'R., 5. rDeslipanae <strong>for</strong> liis concenz a60ut<br />

my war/(since tfie beglnlll·ng. rBeing a teacfier ana as one of tfie p<strong>and</strong> me/n6crs <strong>for</strong> a[{ tfie<br />

semilwrs presentea <strong>at</strong> tfie Institute, lie offerea va[ua6fe comlllmts alia suggestions, wlilcfi<br />

lie[pea me a fot <strong>at</strong> aijferellt stages of my war/(, I am afso tfianliju[ to !Frofessors 'J( L<br />

'J(risfina, rB. 'J(amaiali alla'J(aifas Sarap, <strong>for</strong> tlielr va{ua6(e comments alu! suggestio liS.<br />

I sincerefy e:{press my gr<strong>at</strong>ifu&zess to tfie InstItute <strong>for</strong> Socia{ ana'Ecollomic Crwnge (ISLe)<br />

<strong>for</strong> providing me all opportunity to pursue my aoctora{ studies. I tlian/( tfie preVIous<br />

director Prof :M. C;OVlllaa '1(00 ana tlie presellt airector (Prof C;opaf'J( 7(aaefi.9di<strong>for</strong> lfielr<br />

support ana C/!couragement to my researcli war/(,<br />

:My sincere tlian/(} to !Frof Tom rBrass, 'Editor, 'lJie Jounzaf of Peasant Studies, Prof<br />

:N.s.s. :Narayana, Inaian St<strong>at</strong>isticaf Institute, r]3anga{ore, !Frof '1CP. 'l(pfirajan, Japan ana<br />

Prof Stein JfoUfm, rDepartment of )'lgn'cu{tura[ 'Economics, :Norway, <strong>for</strong> tfieir comments<br />

ana suggest io liS Oil cfiapters 6 ana 7.<br />

I wouUf lili.§ to e:;;press my aeep sense of gr<strong>at</strong>itllae to Professors :M.'R., :Narayall


ellcouragement, liefpfu{ a lid usefu{ discussiolls. I am afso tlia II iifll{ tD alfierf'lw{l\' mem6ers<br />

of 15'EC <strong>for</strong> 6eillg liefpfuC I am gr<strong>at</strong>efu{ to Prof flravil1if 'Pallaganya (,UIll('t'TSlty or<br />

:Maryfallli, VSfl) wlio visited 15'EC <strong>for</strong> a sliort time III 2002 <strong>for</strong> gi'l'lllg lls~ruf suggestiolls<br />

I alSo tliall/(a{{ tlie particip<strong>at</strong>lts of (}3i-allllua{ semitlars presetlted <strong>at</strong> IS'E( <strong>at</strong> nlnous st,lgcs<br />

of my study <strong>for</strong> tfieir constructive commetlts.<br />

fl researcli tfieme of tfie tl<strong>at</strong>ure requires discussioll witli scliofars, 6all/( staff a lid'<br />

illfonn<strong>at</strong>ioll from van'ous sources. I am immensefy gr<strong>at</strong>efu{ to everyolle wlio lias assisted me<br />

ill acliievillg tliis.<br />

I am tliallkju{ to my respolldetlts <strong>for</strong> proviiftng refev<strong>at</strong>lt i'ifonn<strong>at</strong>iotl <strong>at</strong>ld sliantlg tlielt<br />

eJiPerimce wfiife conductIng tlie survey, WlilCIi, itlfact, lie£ped me coIlSldera6fy ltl <strong>at</strong>lafyslllg<br />

tlie d<strong>at</strong>a 011 tfie 06jectives of tlie study.<br />

I am tliankju{ to :Mr. J{.JV. (j(all{]anL1tfulIl, 'R.sgistrar, IS'EC, <strong>at</strong>uf:Mr. 0/. (j(amappa,<br />

)1.ccounts Officer, !SC£C, <strong>for</strong> t!!e!·r fiefp.<br />

I am gr<strong>at</strong>efu{ to tlie pli. ([), Programme Co-ordin<strong>at</strong>ors (IS'EC) <strong>at</strong> differetlt POltltS of time<br />

alld:Mr. 1(s. Narayan <strong>for</strong> tlieir support <strong>at</strong> tlie needed time. I sitlcerefy acli.JlOuIedge ~Hr.<br />

J{.1( flmam<strong>at</strong>li <strong>for</strong>providi'tlg tlie tleeded d<strong>at</strong>a.<br />

I sillcerefy acli.JlOwfedge tfie fiefp alld assistance received from :Mr. 7(nsfilla Cfi<strong>and</strong>r<strong>at</strong>l <strong>at</strong>ld<br />

:Mr. S<strong>at</strong>isli 7(am<strong>at</strong>li ill tlie computer centre <strong>and</strong> tlie mem6ers of LI6rary staff of 15'EC<br />

especia{fy :Mrs. Lifa, 7(afyallappa, 'lIm/(<strong>at</strong>esli alld (j(ajamw. I tliall/( :Mr. 'lis.<br />

Partfiasar<strong>at</strong>liy <strong>for</strong> liis fiefp in edi'tillg of tfie tfiesis. I gr<strong>at</strong>efu{fy acli.JlOwfedge tlie liefp<br />

provided 6y :ManJufa in givill{] tlie tliesis its jina{ sliape.<br />

I taR.! tfiis opportunity to tli<strong>at</strong>ll( my jnelufs <strong>at</strong> IS'EC eSPec/a{fy (}3lianu, :M11ll~<br />

(Deept/~<br />

flmar, ([)eepi/(a, Sita/(<strong>at</strong>lta, ([)amilll~ S<strong>at</strong>ya, Pr<strong>at</strong>uslina, (}3initlia, SrideVl~ flsliisli, 'l(sliyama,<br />

Su60dli, Puma, ([)ukjia, J{ruslii, fltl<strong>and</strong>a 'lIadive£u, (}3adn~ {Bi/(asli, (jlta''laya, Sar6al/l <strong>at</strong>ld<br />

otliers <strong>for</strong> tlieir kjluf liefp <strong>at</strong> differetlt pOints of time. I am alSo tli<strong>at</strong>liifu{ to )llI<strong>at</strong>ltli,<br />

,/(nslitlagouda, :Madliavi, Saclil alld Jugafjor tliClr getlerous liefp.<br />

Last 6ut /lot feast, I am tliallkju{ to my pare'lts, 6rotliers, sisters, <strong>at</strong>ld my wife <strong>for</strong> tliClr<br />

COllSt<strong>at</strong>lt morae support Itl fu(fi[(ztlg my dream of compfeting tlie pli.·v' tliesls.<br />

qagan {}3inari Sanu


Chapter 1<br />

INTRODUCTION<br />

St<strong>at</strong>ement of the Problem<br />

A majority of the cultiv<strong>at</strong>ors find borrowing necessary as their own<br />

farm savings are inadequ<strong>at</strong>e to <strong>finance</strong> vanous agricultural<br />

development activities. It has been argued th<strong>at</strong> credit provides<br />

comm<strong>and</strong> over resources <strong>and</strong> facilit<strong>at</strong>es the needed liquidity to the<br />

farmers (Lipton 1976). Credit is assumed to be helpful <strong>for</strong> changing<br />

the composition <strong>and</strong> distribution of production in favour of deficit<br />

producers. Improved access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit is supposed to shift rural<br />

borrowing from in<strong>for</strong>mal market to <strong>for</strong>mal institutions, increasing the<br />

use<br />

... __ 1 ____ ' __ _<br />

LCL.HHUIUg,y, leading [0 increased<br />

production <strong>and</strong> higher income <strong>for</strong> the rural poor (Donald 1976; Sarap<br />

1990).<br />

With the introduction of new agricultural technology in India in<br />

the mid-1970s, the need <strong>for</strong> improving the quality of institutional<br />

credit (timely <strong>and</strong> adequ<strong>at</strong>e loan amount) to <strong>agriculture</strong> \\'as largely<br />

felt. With the assumption th<strong>at</strong> the new agricultural technology was<br />

scale neutral, it was felt th<strong>at</strong> increased access among the marginal<br />

farmers to credit would improve the employment potential <strong>and</strong><br />

contribute to better income distribution in rural areas.<br />

Taking the above into account, many committees recommcnckcl<br />

improvement in the outreach of the <strong>for</strong>mal financial institutions in<br />

favour of rural areas, <strong>and</strong> small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers. The<br />

n<strong>at</strong>ionalis<strong>at</strong>ion of banks in 1969, various policies aimed ,,1 s()cia!<br />

banking <strong>and</strong> the establishment of Regional Rural Banks III 1 "7,'1


esulted in an increase in the number of bank branches in rur"l<br />

areas. During the mid-1980s, the m<strong>and</strong><strong>at</strong>oI'- priorit\, sector lending<br />

\'.-as introduced to ensure adequ<strong>at</strong>e credit flow to hitherto neglected<br />

sectors such as <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> alike. Undeniably, these resulted in a<br />

vast network of rural financial institutions, <strong>and</strong> a rapid growth c;f<br />

lending to all sectors including <strong>agriculture</strong>.<br />

However, the following problems <strong>and</strong> deficiencies 111 the rural<br />

credit delivery system were also noticed,<br />

:J The rural banking system in India made tremendous quantit<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

achievement by neglecting the qualit<strong>at</strong>iye aspects of the credit<br />

delivery system (Shivamaggi 2000), The empirical studies show<br />

th<strong>at</strong> institutional c;rFdit was Hccessed by the ,vel! to do among n .H"3.!<br />

people (Adams <strong>and</strong> Vogel 1986). Further, the Indian policy makers<br />

were unable to arrive <strong>at</strong> a banking structure <strong>and</strong> oper<strong>at</strong>ional<br />

system, which was suitable <strong>for</strong> the credit needs of the<br />

agriculturists (Shivamaggi 2000).<br />

:J The inequalities in the banking system across the regIOns <strong>and</strong><br />

social classes persisted (Bell 1990). This was because of the<br />

insistence on coll<strong>at</strong>eral (Sarap 1991) which could not be prO\'ided<br />

by the poor, complic<strong>at</strong>ed administr<strong>at</strong>ion proced u re s, lon a<br />

"<br />

distances from the villages to the branches, the cultural gap<br />

between bank officials <strong>and</strong> the poor, political interference,<br />

inflexible lending policies <strong>and</strong> procedures, lack of prO\'ision <strong>for</strong><br />

consumption credit <strong>and</strong> a widespread belief th<strong>at</strong> the poor were<br />

non-bankable.


J<br />

Although some of the rural poor obtained credit from the Form;l!<br />

Rural Banking System (FRBS), they found th<strong>at</strong> the credit \\';j"<br />

neither timely nor adequ<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> their needs (RaJasekhar <strong>and</strong><br />

Vyasulu 1990). The disbursal of loans without assessing the<br />

feasibility, viability <strong>and</strong> entrepreneurial experience of borrowers led<br />

to the problem of fungibilityl. There were also problems \\'ithin the<br />

banking system such as lack of linkages between credit <strong>and</strong><br />

production, extension, marketing, etc.<br />

::J<br />

The <strong>for</strong>mal banking system began to face problems of higher<br />

transaction costs 2 (due to lending small amounts to large numbers<br />

of borrowers) <strong>and</strong> recurring losses 1I1 the l<strong>at</strong>e 1980s. The<br />

managerial inadequacies within the banking system also caused<br />

problems (Vyasulu <strong>and</strong> Rajasekhar 1993).<br />

::J<br />

All the above culmin<strong>at</strong>ed in an alarming growth in overdue<br />

payments 3 . This, in turn, adversely affected the recycling of credit,<br />

<strong>and</strong> led to lower profit margins (Singh 1991; Rajasekhar <strong>and</strong><br />

1 It implies the process of financial substitution. For a detmled discussion, see, Von<br />

Pischke <strong>and</strong> Adams (1980), Ladman <strong>and</strong> Tinnermeier (1981), <strong>and</strong> Adams <strong>and</strong><br />

Vogel (1986).<br />

2 A study made by S<strong>at</strong>ish <strong>and</strong> Swamin<strong>at</strong>h (1989) found th<strong>at</strong> the average cost of<br />

lending of CBs, Primary Agricultural Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive Societies (PACSs), RRl:ls <strong>and</strong><br />

L<strong>and</strong> Development Banks (LOBs) was gre<strong>at</strong>er than the average interest II1come<br />

from the agricu1tural sector. Discussing the \'lability of rural credn institutions.<br />

Gadgil (1986) emphasised the high cost of transaction, <strong>and</strong> the mounting loan<br />

delinquencies, which were eroding the strength of the rural cft"dit institutions.<br />

Desai <strong>and</strong> Namboodiri (1992) found th<strong>at</strong> all Rural Financial InstitutIons (1-11'151.<br />

except PACSs, prevailed under constant returns to scale (CI~S) in theIr transactio,"<br />

cost from the period 1961 to 1981. PACSs suffered from scale d,seconomlCS II1<br />

their transaction costs <strong>for</strong> the saIne reference period.<br />

J The causes of overdue payment haye been briefl.\" disruss('ri in l-\hcs;o (1 YS91 Ti:-::"<br />

issues rel<strong>at</strong>ing to overdues, default r<strong>at</strong>e, political Intervention 1:: sanction ar:c<br />

recoveries of loans. <strong>and</strong> defective lending policies ha\'e bee;; discussr'd ]T'.:<br />

Ra]asekhar <strong>and</strong> V,'asulu (1990). \'Yasulu <strong>and</strong> I


Vyasulu 1991). Many Commercial Banks (CBs), Regional Rural<br />

Banks (RRBs) <strong>and</strong> co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives were consequently incurring<br />

losses.<br />

This led to mounting pressure on the government from Indian<br />

bankers (<strong>and</strong> some outside agencies) to initi<strong>at</strong>e banking sector re<strong>for</strong>ms<br />

<strong>for</strong> the financial viability of the FRBS. Yielding to this pressure, the<br />

Government of India appointed the Narasimham Committee in 1991,<br />

which recommended measures to improve efficiency, profitability <strong>and</strong><br />

viability of the banking sector. The recommend<strong>at</strong>ions of the<br />

Narasimham Committee relevant to the present study were to reduce<br />

the share of credit to the priority sector from 40 per cent to 10 per<br />

cent of aggreg<strong>at</strong>e bank credit, deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of interest r<strong>at</strong>es, abolition<br />

of branch licensing, gradual phasing out of directed credit<br />

programmes, closing down of loss-making bank branches <strong>and</strong> so on.<br />

The committee was of the view th<strong>at</strong> easy <strong>and</strong> timely access to credit<br />

was far more important than its cost. Gradual reduction of the Cash<br />

t{eserve R<strong>at</strong>io (eRR) <strong>and</strong> St<strong>at</strong>utory Liquidity R<strong>at</strong>io (SLR) to enable the<br />

banks to have larger quantum of loanable funds was also<br />

recommended. Besides, the committee took the view th<strong>at</strong> the growth<br />

of <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> small industry reached a point where banks on the<br />

basis of their commercial judgement were in a position to meet the<br />

legitim<strong>at</strong>e productive needs.<br />

The Gupta Committee, set up in 1998, to examine the issues<br />

rel<strong>at</strong>ing to the quality of credit delivered by the banking system,<br />

highlighted the issue of how an improvement in the quality of lending<br />

helps the banking system to become financially viable. The committec<br />

suggested measures aimed <strong>at</strong> simplific<strong>at</strong>ion of proccdures <strong>for</strong>


agricultural credit <strong>and</strong> identific<strong>at</strong>ion of constraints faced bv the<br />

commercial banks to increase the flow of credit.<br />

The government did not accept all the recommend<strong>at</strong>ions made<br />

by the Narasimham Committee (1991), especially the one on reducing<br />

the target <strong>for</strong> priority sector. Nevertheless, it appears th<strong>at</strong>, the str<strong>at</strong>egy<br />

followed by Reserve Bank of India (RBI) was to keep the overall share<br />

of credit to priority sector <strong>at</strong> 40 per cent, <strong>and</strong> broaden the scope of<br />

priority sector to encourage diversion from direct priority sector<br />

lending. Since September 1990, interest r<strong>at</strong>es to the ultim<strong>at</strong>e<br />

borrowers were r<strong>at</strong>ionalised by the RBI. This policy was based on the<br />

Narasimham committee recommend<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>for</strong> deregul<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong><br />

abolition of concessional interest r<strong>at</strong>es so th<strong>at</strong> all r<strong>at</strong>es becamF<br />

positive in real terms.<br />

It can, there<strong>for</strong>e, be st<strong>at</strong>ed th<strong>at</strong> the banking sector re<strong>for</strong>ms may<br />

have the following positive as well as neg<strong>at</strong>ive impact on the credit<br />

flow to <strong>agriculture</strong>.<br />

[J Increased availability of funds to banks as a result of reduced CRR<br />

<strong>and</strong> SLR may have a positive impact on credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

provided the banks are unable to find altern<strong>at</strong>ive <strong>and</strong> profitable<br />

non-agricultural avenues to disburse the credit.<br />

:J The de-regul<strong>at</strong>ion of interest r<strong>at</strong>es may increase the credit flow to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> because it has been often argued th<strong>at</strong> wh<strong>at</strong> m<strong>at</strong>ters to<br />

the farmers is the access to credit r<strong>at</strong>her than its costs. With deregul<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

of interest r<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong> the concomitant increase in returns<br />

to banks, one can expect th<strong>at</strong> the quality of credit delivery system<br />

may be improved <strong>and</strong> the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> stepped up.


o The introduction of credit norms rel<strong>at</strong>ing to profitability are also<br />

expected to increase the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong>, provided<br />

bankers perceive th<strong>at</strong> agricultural lending is profitable.<br />

o The closure of loss-making branches may, however, lead to<br />

reduction in credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong>. This is because most of the<br />

loss-making branches during the pre-re<strong>for</strong>m period were found to<br />

be loc<strong>at</strong>ed in rural <strong>and</strong> semi-urban areas. If these branches are<br />

closed, the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> may come down 4 .<br />

o The widening scope of priority sector may result in the gre<strong>at</strong>er<br />

availability of credit to priority sector, in general, <strong>and</strong> agricultural<br />

sector, in particular.<br />

The above lead to the following questions: Wh<strong>at</strong> have been the<br />

trends in credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong>? Was there any difference in the<br />

credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> between the pre-re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>and</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m periods?<br />

Wh<strong>at</strong> factors governed the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> during the prere<strong>for</strong>m<br />

<strong>and</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m periods? How did the policy of widening the scope<br />

of priority sector bank lending enhance the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong>?<br />

Did the r<strong>at</strong>ionalis<strong>at</strong>ion of interest r<strong>at</strong>es contribute to more credit flow<br />

to <strong>agriculture</strong>? Wh<strong>at</strong> was the impact of profit-oriented lending norms<br />

on the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong>? Wh<strong>at</strong> was the impact of closure of<br />

rural bank branches on the provision of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong>?<br />

4 In the earlier role of 'social banking', banks became the instruments of the st<strong>at</strong>e<br />

in the development process, \\:hich are now oriented towards profit maximis<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

which guides the evalu<strong>at</strong>ion of pre-re<strong>for</strong>m branch licensing polic\·. The sa\"lngs<br />

r<strong>at</strong>e in India, in fact, is positively associ<strong>at</strong>ed with the availability of bank<br />

branches. The evidence shows th<strong>at</strong> rural branches have increased their share of<br />

deposits <strong>and</strong> credit between 1969 <strong>and</strong> 1996 from 3.0 <strong>and</strong> 0.2 per cent to 15.4<br />

<strong>and</strong> 12.4 per cent. respectiveh' (Kohli 1999). For more detailed anah·sls. see. I'r ..<br />

(1988). P<strong>and</strong>it (1991). <strong>and</strong> Desai (1993).<br />

(,


Conceptual Framework<br />

The present study seeks to analyse these issues <strong>at</strong> both <strong>macro</strong> (all<br />

India <strong>and</strong> st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>levels</strong>) <strong>and</strong> <strong>micro</strong> (household) <strong>levels</strong>. Finance to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>at</strong> the <strong>macro</strong> level depends upon the collective impact of<br />

policies rel<strong>at</strong>ing to agricultural credit, in general, interest r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong><br />

norms rel<strong>at</strong>ing to profitability, in particular. The policy on <strong>finance</strong> <strong>at</strong><br />

the <strong>macro</strong> level primarily concerns with the level of credit flow to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>, terms <strong>and</strong> conditions under which it is made available,<br />

alloc<strong>at</strong>ion of credit between sub-sectors (production <strong>and</strong> investment<br />

credit) within <strong>agriculture</strong> to achieve production efficiency <strong>and</strong> so on.<br />

Besides, <strong>macro</strong> credit policies are concerned with the provision of<br />

cheap, adequ<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> timely credit (<strong>for</strong> both production <strong>and</strong><br />

investment) to the needy farmers. encouraging them to adopt nt'w<br />

agricultural technology, <strong>and</strong> pre <strong>and</strong> post-appraisal of loan<br />

disbursement, etc.<br />

These policies, In general, give guideline to <strong>micro</strong> level<br />

institutional <strong>finance</strong> agenCies having direct contact with the<br />

borrowers. The flow of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>at</strong> this level depends on<br />

financial feasibility of the concerned project, mechanisms of client<br />

selection, repayment per<strong>for</strong>mance of the borrower, ability to provide<br />

coll<strong>at</strong>eral security, cost of lending, cost of borrowing <strong>and</strong> so on.<br />

There<strong>for</strong>e, it appears th<strong>at</strong> <strong>macro</strong> level credit policies may not address<br />

the problems rel<strong>at</strong>ing to agricultural credit <strong>at</strong> the <strong>micro</strong> level. Hence,<br />

an examin<strong>at</strong>ion of the constraints faced by the farmers to access<br />

institutional credit <strong>at</strong> the <strong>micro</strong> level is essential. Furthermore, many<br />

changes in agricultural credit policies have taken place during the<br />

re<strong>for</strong>m period (see, Chapter 2). which may have affected the flow of<br />

7


credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> directly or indirectly <strong>at</strong> both <strong>macro</strong> <strong>and</strong> mIcro<br />

<strong>levels</strong>.<br />

Credit Accessibility Problems<br />

It is well known fact th<strong>at</strong> rural financial markets are imperfect in<br />

n<strong>at</strong>ure. Cost involved in obtaining in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion on potential clients,<br />

long distance from the village to the bank branches, the cultural gap<br />

between bank official <strong>and</strong> the poor, inflexible lending policies are some<br />

of the critical elements th<strong>at</strong> can restrict the outreach of rural financial<br />

institutions. Besides, rural farmers are faced with a number of<br />

constraints th<strong>at</strong> restrict their access to a given supply of <strong>for</strong>mal credit.<br />

The liter<strong>at</strong>ure on credit markets explains the outreach from<br />

supply side perspective <strong>and</strong> access from the viewpoint of the potential<br />

borrower, wherein both indic<strong>at</strong>e the same thing, i.e., who is obtaining<br />

credit. The term "accessibility" is used purposefully in this study to<br />

emphasise the link between bank-rel<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>and</strong> household-rel<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

factors to explain why certain households borrow, while others do not.<br />

In the context of credit accessibility, the problem has been looked <strong>at</strong><br />

from both breadth (the number of clients reached) <strong>and</strong> depth (type of<br />

clients reached) of outreach. To study these two aspects, both supply<br />

as well as dem<strong>and</strong>-rel<strong>at</strong>ed factors have been taken into account (see,<br />

<strong>for</strong> example, Sarap 1990, <strong>and</strong> Hashuliza <strong>and</strong> Kydd 1996).<br />

Furthermore, in the context of "accessibility", the issue of<br />

outreach (i.e., in terms of both breadth <strong>and</strong> depth) <strong>and</strong> sustainabilitv<br />

of financial institutions are often deb<strong>at</strong>ed (Yaron et I 1997). Critics<br />

note th<strong>at</strong> too much of importance to the breadth of outreach resulted<br />

in the neglect of the depth of outreach (Morduch 2000). The possible<br />

8


trade-offs between sustainability <strong>and</strong> the depth of outreach ha\'e been.<br />

there<strong>for</strong>e, the subject of an ongoing discussion in the rural credit<br />

markets (Rhyne 1998).<br />

The <strong>for</strong>egoing discussion suggests th<strong>at</strong> importance to the<br />

breadth of outreach may endanger the sustainability (viability) of the<br />

financial institutions. But, the reverse may not necessarily be true. In<br />

other words, if the sustainability is the main agenda then the depth of<br />

outreach seems to be crucial. If the credit transaction is looked from a<br />

lender's perspective, it is the objective of banks th<strong>at</strong> determine the<br />

flow of credit, <strong>and</strong>, in turn, its access by different c<strong>at</strong>egories of<br />

farmers.<br />

There<strong>for</strong>e, the credit transaction can be analysed from the<br />

characteristics of the supply versus dem<strong>and</strong> side. Since credit<br />

generally involves a time gap between the point when credit is given,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the future point when credit is repaid with interest, anything may<br />

happen in-between these two time points. So, the credit transaction<br />

involves interpersonal trust between the borrower <strong>and</strong> the lender.<br />

However, if the credit transaction IS looked from a lender's<br />

perspective, one can anticip<strong>at</strong>e pre-contractual (<strong>at</strong> the point of<br />

disbursement of loan), <strong>and</strong> post-contractual problems (<strong>at</strong> the point of<br />

loan repayment). The <strong>for</strong>mer brings the issue of adverse selection (i.e.,<br />

the fear of selecting a bad borrower), credit-worthiness <strong>and</strong> screening<br />

of the borrower. In the case of l<strong>at</strong>ter, a lender faces the problem of<br />

wilful <strong>and</strong> non-wilful default. Given these problems, wh<strong>at</strong> governs<br />

access to institutional credit <strong>for</strong> some peasant households but not<br />

others? A conceptual framework summarising the factors influencing<br />

access to credit is provided in Figure 1. 1.<br />

9


Figure 1.1: Factors th<strong>at</strong> Determine the Accessibility of Credit<br />

Financial Institutions<br />

Farm Household<br />

- objective of - beinfJ part of th<br />

the financial ~~~~~ service area<br />

products<br />

- capacity to take<br />

- mechanism of a loan<br />

borrower<br />

- willingness to take<br />

selection<br />

a loan<br />

Credit Outreach<br />

credit of the financial institutions are their objectives of the financial<br />

products, which may have positive or neg<strong>at</strong>ive effects on breadth <strong>and</strong><br />

depth of outreach. Objectives like reduction in cost of lending or<br />

specific<strong>at</strong>ion of target group can have a neg<strong>at</strong>ive effect on the breadth<br />

of outreach. The second c<strong>at</strong>egory of factors th<strong>at</strong> determine<br />

accessibility of credit product is the mechanism of borrower selection.<br />

To select a borrower they need either a guarantor or physical coll<strong>at</strong>eral<br />

or both. Elsewhere, it has been argued th<strong>at</strong> a guarantor can be<br />

considered as an important <strong>for</strong>m of social coll<strong>at</strong>eral, which IS more<br />

important than physical coll<strong>at</strong>eral (Vaessen 2001). Coll<strong>at</strong>eral<br />

requirements may have neg<strong>at</strong>ive impact on depth of outreach.<br />

From the borrower's perspective, factors th<strong>at</strong> influence access to<br />

credit can be put under the following three broad c<strong>at</strong>egories. (a) a<br />

borrower must be living in the area of oper<strong>at</strong>ion, (b) a borrower must<br />

have the capacity to take a loan, <strong>and</strong> (c) a borrower should be willing<br />

10


to take a loan. Capacity to take a loan refers to the household's<br />

capacity to meet the <strong>for</strong>mal selection criteria <strong>and</strong> banker's additional<br />

expect<strong>at</strong>ion on repayment capacity. In order to win over the lender's<br />

confidence, the borrower must be in a position to s<strong>at</strong>isfy the lender<br />

with some coll<strong>at</strong>eral both tangible <strong>and</strong> intangible. Willingness to take<br />

a loan depends upon the transaction costs, availability of credit from<br />

altern<strong>at</strong>ive sources with more <strong>at</strong>tractive terms <strong>and</strong> conditions, interest<br />

r<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong> so on.<br />

The above theoretical framework on accessibility of institutional<br />

credit (Figure 1.1) expects th<strong>at</strong> many factors influencing the credit<br />

accessibility are <strong>at</strong> work. Since access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit is not common<br />

to all c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers, it is necessary to analyse the factors th<strong>at</strong><br />

account <strong>for</strong> vari<strong>at</strong>ions in the credit flow. Even if some farmers are<br />

accessing <strong>for</strong>mal credit, is it sufficient to meet their requirement? If it<br />

is not, under wh<strong>at</strong> conditions do bankers decide the credit limit to a<br />

particular farmer? If the disbursed loan amount is largely influenced<br />

by supply-side factors, a larger gap between supply <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

credit is the likely possibility. Furthermore, the magnitude of this gap<br />

may vary across different size classes of l<strong>and</strong>holdings.<br />

Objectives of the Study<br />

In the light of these issues, the present study on credit flow to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> derives its relevance <strong>and</strong> has the following objectives.<br />

• To study <strong>macro</strong> (all India) level trends of institutional credit to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>and</strong> after the introduction of the banking<br />

sector re<strong>for</strong>m, <strong>and</strong> analyse the contributing factors.<br />

• To study dis-aggreg<strong>at</strong>ed trends (st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> district level within<br />

Orissa) <strong>and</strong> contributing factors to the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong>.<br />

II


• To analyse the factors th<strong>at</strong> account <strong>for</strong> vari<strong>at</strong>ions in the flow of<br />

credit <strong>at</strong> the household level.<br />

• To measure credit gap among farm hOllseholds across the size<br />

class of l<strong>and</strong>holdings.<br />

Scope of the Study<br />

The <strong>macro</strong> level analysis on the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong>, has been<br />

confined to all India, while the st<strong>at</strong>e level analysis to 14 major st<strong>at</strong>es.<br />

These st<strong>at</strong>es consist of Andhra Pradesh, Bihar (undivided), Gujar<strong>at</strong>,<br />

Haryana, Karn<strong>at</strong>aka, Kerala, Madhya Pradesh (undivided)<br />

Maharashtra, Orissa, Punjab, Rajasthan, Tamil Nadu, Uttar Pradesh<br />

(undivided) <strong>and</strong> West Bengal. The r<strong>at</strong>ionale <strong>for</strong> the selection of these<br />

st<strong>at</strong>es lies in the fact th<strong>at</strong> they account <strong>for</strong> 93 per cent of the<br />

popul<strong>at</strong>IOn <strong>and</strong> ':11.5 per cent of the Net Domestic Product (NDP) in the<br />

country (see, Rao et al 1999). Besides, these st<strong>at</strong>es have been<br />

accounting, on an average, 84.7 per cent of the total deposits in the<br />

country through Scheduled Commercial Banks (SCBs) including RRB<br />

<strong>for</strong> the last twenty years. Out of the total agricultural credit provided<br />

in the country through SCBs <strong>and</strong> RRBs, on an average, 95 per cent of<br />

it goes to these st<strong>at</strong>es (RBI, various years). The hill st<strong>at</strong>es of north <strong>and</strong><br />

north-eastern parts of India, which are considered as special c<strong>at</strong>egory<br />

st<strong>at</strong>es by the Planning Commission, have been excluded from the<br />

analysis due to significant differences in the structure of these<br />

economies from the rest of the st<strong>at</strong>es. It is also worth mentioning th<strong>at</strong><br />

in these hill st<strong>at</strong>es the important sources of income are government<br />

activities <strong>and</strong> there has hardly been any manufacturing base (Rao et<br />

al 1999).<br />

12


The district level analysis has been done <strong>for</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e of Orissa<br />

because of its distinctive character of backwardness'- The Economic<br />

Survey of Orissa <strong>for</strong> the year 2000-01 notes with concern th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

credit deposit r<strong>at</strong>i0 6 (CDR) in the st<strong>at</strong>e declined from 80.59 per cent in<br />

1991 to 39.75 per cent in 1999-00, while per-bank branch popul<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

increased from 15,200 persons to 16,300 during the same period. The<br />

reduced CDR might be adversely effecting the credit flow to different<br />

sectors in the economy. It was, there<strong>for</strong>e, noted th<strong>at</strong> there was a need<br />

to look into the ground level credit flow to the different sectors in the<br />

st<strong>at</strong>e, in general, <strong>and</strong> to <strong>agriculture</strong>, in particular.<br />

The <strong>micro</strong>-level analysis has been carried in the specific context<br />

of Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district, Orissa. Loc<strong>at</strong>ed in the western part of the st<strong>at</strong>e,<br />

this district IS known 111 India <strong>for</strong> widespread poverty <strong>and</strong><br />

backwardness. For the <strong>micro</strong> level analysis, d<strong>at</strong>a from four different<br />

bank branches <strong>and</strong> 200 farm households (falling within the service<br />

area of these banks) have been collected. Since farmers in the study<br />

area hardly get crop loans during Rabi session, the <strong>micro</strong> level<br />

analysis is restricted to only Kharif crops <strong>for</strong> the year 2001-02.<br />

The secondary d<strong>at</strong>a <strong>for</strong> undertaking analysis <strong>at</strong> all India, st<strong>at</strong>e<br />

<strong>and</strong> districts level were collected from the Report on Currency <strong>and</strong><br />

Finance (RBI), Banking St<strong>at</strong>istics (RBI), Fertiliser St<strong>at</strong>istics (the<br />

Fertiliser Associ<strong>at</strong>ion of India), Indian Agricultural St<strong>at</strong>istics (Ministry<br />

5 An examin<strong>at</strong>ion of the d<strong>at</strong>a on <strong>levels</strong> of per-capita income, industrialis<strong>at</strong>ion,<br />

urbanis<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> literacy r<strong>at</strong>e shows th<strong>at</strong> this st<strong>at</strong>e falls into the c<strong>at</strong>egory of<br />

'backward' .<br />

6 The CDR in Orissa was well below the all India average of 57.05 per cent in 1999-<br />

00, <strong>and</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>es with better CDR than Orissa included Tamil Nadu (88.0 %),<br />

Maharashtra (83.79 %), Andhra Pradesh (63.60 %), Karn<strong>at</strong>aka (61.01 %), Gujar<strong>at</strong><br />

(49.85 %), Madhya Pradesh (49.17 %), Rajasthan 146.69 %), West Bengal (45.17),<br />

<strong>and</strong> Kerala 142.29 %). This in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion was collected from Bankmg St<strong>at</strong>istIcs.<br />

Quarterly H<strong>and</strong>out, RBI (March 2000).<br />

13


\-1<br />

of Agriculture, Government of India) <strong>and</strong> St<strong>at</strong>istical Abstract (Central<br />

St<strong>at</strong>istical Organis<strong>at</strong>ion, Department of St<strong>at</strong>istics <strong>and</strong> Programme<br />

Implement<strong>at</strong>ion, Government of India). For the analysis on trends in<br />

credit flow in Orissa st<strong>at</strong>e, d<strong>at</strong>a were collected from Stale Level<br />

Bankers Committee Meetings (Agenda Notes) <strong>and</strong> Orissa Agricultural<br />

St<strong>at</strong>istics (Director<strong>at</strong>e of Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Food Production, Orissa,<br />

Bhubaneswar).<br />

Since the banking sector re<strong>for</strong>ms have not made any impact on<br />

the financial p<strong>at</strong>tern of Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives, the study is exclusively based<br />

on the <strong>finance</strong> provided by the Scheduled Commercial Banks to<br />

agricultural sector. The Scheduled Commercial Banks consist of St<strong>at</strong>e<br />

Bank or india <strong>and</strong> its Associ<strong>at</strong>es, N<strong>at</strong>ionalised Banks, Foreign Banks,<br />

Regional Rural Banks, <strong>and</strong> Other Scheduled Commercial Banks.<br />

In the case of <strong>micro</strong> level (households), analysis emphasis was<br />

gIven on the loan provided by <strong>for</strong>mal institutions. Nevertheless, to<br />

measure the credit-gap <strong>and</strong> to capture the dependency of the studygroup<br />

on in<strong>for</strong>mal sources of credit, loans provided by non-<strong>for</strong>mal<br />

agencies have been taken into account.<br />

Chapter Scheme<br />

The study comprises eight chapters.<br />

The second chapter provides a review of liter<strong>at</strong>ure on issues relevant<br />

to agricultural credit. This chapter by focusing on policies, progress<br />

<strong>and</strong> problems of agricultural credit in India, exammes the major<br />

directions in rural banking <strong>and</strong> credit policies during the post-


independence period, <strong>and</strong> the policy per<strong>for</strong>mance especially in respect<br />

of credit flow to agricultural sector.<br />

Chapter three, on "Credit Flow to Agriculture: Trends <strong>and</strong><br />

Contributing Factors <strong>at</strong> All India Level", analyses the trends in credit<br />

flow in terms of percentage <strong>and</strong> growth r<strong>at</strong>es, <strong>and</strong> contributing factors<br />

with the help of the ordinary least squares method.<br />

The fourth chapter covers the st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> district level analysis on<br />

the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> during pre-re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>and</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m periods. In<br />

this chapter also, a trend analysis in terms of growth r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong><br />

percentage has been made to examine the flow of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong>.<br />

It has to be mentioned here th<strong>at</strong> the proportion of net bank credit may<br />

not be able to explain the actual situ<strong>at</strong>ion in so far as the flow of<br />

agricultural credit <strong>at</strong> the ground level is concerned. There<strong>for</strong>e, the<br />

availability of credit per hectare of gross cropped area has been<br />

calcul<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>at</strong> both st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> districts <strong>levels</strong> to analyse the vari<strong>at</strong>ions in<br />

the supply of agricultural credit. Factors contributing to the vari<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

in the supply of credit per hectare of gross cropped area have been<br />

analysed with the help of Fixed <strong>and</strong> R<strong>and</strong>om Effect models <strong>at</strong> both<br />

st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> district <strong>levels</strong>.<br />

The fifth chapter explains the impact of <strong>macro</strong> level agricultural<br />

credit policy <strong>at</strong> <strong>micro</strong> level. To assess the impact of these policies on<br />

the p<strong>at</strong>tern of supply of credit to different sectors, the in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion \\·as<br />

collected from four bank branches (two each belonging to commercial<br />

bank <strong>and</strong> RRB c<strong>at</strong>egories) loc<strong>at</strong>ed in advanced <strong>and</strong> backward blocks of<br />

Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district in Orissa. The factors accounting <strong>for</strong> vari<strong>at</strong>ions in<br />

the flow of credit to farm households have been analysed in the sixth<br />

IS


chapter. It is worth mentioning here th<strong>at</strong> an analysis on the vari<strong>at</strong>ions<br />

in the flow of credit can be undertaken either in terms of access to<br />

credit or amount obtained across the size classes of l<strong>and</strong>holdings. In<br />

this context, the farmers' access to institutional credit is estim<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

using the binary choice (Pro bit) model. The factors determining the<br />

amount of institutional credit lent were estim<strong>at</strong>ed with the help of<br />

Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) methods. However, the factors<br />

determining access to the credit to certain farmers is not r<strong>and</strong>om. In<br />

order to correct this problem of selectivity bias, Heckman two-step<br />

procedure has been used. In the first step, the Inverse Mills R<strong>at</strong>io (A)<br />

has been calcul<strong>at</strong>ed from the Pro bit equ<strong>at</strong>ion, <strong>and</strong> in the second step,<br />

this has been introduced as an additional explan<strong>at</strong>ory variable in the<br />

eqll<strong>at</strong>ion on determinants of credit.<br />

The credit delivery system <strong>and</strong> the extent of credit-gap <strong>for</strong><br />

different c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers have been discussed in the seventh<br />

chapter. Given the self-<strong>finance</strong> capacity <strong>and</strong> per acre paid-out cost,<br />

the actual <strong>and</strong> rel<strong>at</strong>ive credit-gaps have been calcul<strong>at</strong>ed across the<br />

size-classes of l<strong>and</strong>holdings. The coping str<strong>at</strong>egies adopted by farmers<br />

in the study area have also been highlighted.<br />

The<br />

last chapter summanses the study, <strong>and</strong> discusses<br />

conclusions <strong>and</strong> policy implic<strong>at</strong>ions.<br />

16


Chapter 2<br />

POLICIES, PROGRESS AND PROBLEMS IN<br />

AGRICULTURAL CREDIT: THEORETICAL ISSUES<br />

Introduction<br />

There is a realis<strong>at</strong>ion In most of the low-income countries th<strong>at</strong><br />

agricultural credit is an important element in their development<br />

ef<strong>for</strong>ts. The popularity of credit is partly due to the notion th<strong>at</strong><br />

loans are necessary to acceler<strong>at</strong>e technological change in farming,<br />

<strong>and</strong> th<strong>at</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal credit is required to free farmers from their<br />

dependency on unorganised sector. The agricultural credit policies,<br />

in general, aim to have positive influence on the total volume of<br />

institutional credit, the use of agricultural inputs, investment on<br />

machinery <strong>and</strong> irrig<strong>at</strong>ion, agricultural output <strong>and</strong> productivity,<br />

rural income distribution <strong>and</strong> so on. These policies also aim to<br />

direct a larger share of institutional credit to the 'weaker' sections<br />

<strong>for</strong> their development.<br />

The declared objectives of the public policy with regard to<br />

rural credit, in general, <strong>and</strong> agricultural credit, in particular, in the<br />

post-Independent India were, there<strong>for</strong>e, "to ensure th<strong>at</strong> sufficient<br />

<strong>and</strong> timely credit <strong>at</strong> reasonable r<strong>at</strong>e of interest is made available to<br />

as large a segment of the rural popul<strong>at</strong>ion as possible" (Rangarajan<br />

1996). To achieve this objective, the expansion of <strong>for</strong>mal sector<br />

lending institutions, directed lending <strong>and</strong> subsidised credit policies<br />

were introduced <strong>at</strong> different points of time. A multi-agency<br />

approach was adopted as a n<strong>at</strong>ional policy <strong>for</strong> institutional credit<br />

where co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives, Commercial Banks <strong>and</strong> Regional Rural Banks<br />

were pressed into service to ensure sufficient agricultural <strong>and</strong> rural<br />

credit flow. Taking different types of farm credit needs into account,<br />

17


the provision of a range of credit services (long <strong>and</strong> short-term, <strong>and</strong><br />

large <strong>and</strong> small loans) was envisaged in the policies.<br />

This chapter discusses the major policy directions, progress<br />

<strong>and</strong> problems of institutional <strong>finance</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong>. For this<br />

purpose, the period 1951-52 to 2000 has been divided into three<br />

sub-periods, viz., 1951-52 to 1969-70, 1970-71 to 1989-91 <strong>and</strong><br />

1991-92 to 1999-2000. The r<strong>at</strong>ionale <strong>for</strong> sub-periodis<strong>at</strong>ion has been<br />

the n<strong>at</strong>ionalis<strong>at</strong>ion of commercial banks in 1969 <strong>and</strong> the<br />

introduction of banking sector re<strong>for</strong>ms in 1991.<br />

Phases of Banking Policies<br />

The Pre-N<strong>at</strong>ionalis<strong>at</strong>ion Period (1951-52 to 1969-70)<br />

During 1950s, co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives <strong>and</strong> government were the mam<br />

providers of institutional <strong>finance</strong> to <strong>agriculture</strong>, though they<br />

accounted <strong>for</strong> a small share of the total credit (D<strong>and</strong>eker <strong>and</strong> Wadia<br />

1989; K<strong>at</strong>ula <strong>and</strong> Gul<strong>at</strong>i 1992). According to the Report of the All<br />

India Rural Credit Survey Committee (1954) appointed by the RBI,<br />

out of the total amount borrowed by the cultiv<strong>at</strong>ors from different<br />

credit agencies (both <strong>for</strong>mal <strong>and</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal), <strong>for</strong>mal agenCIes<br />

accounted <strong>for</strong> only 7.3 per cent. Of this, the commercial banks<br />

provided only 0.9 per cent, while government <strong>and</strong> co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives<br />

accounted <strong>for</strong> the rest. This meant th<strong>at</strong> as much as 92.7 per cent of<br />

the credit was provided by the in<strong>for</strong>mal sector consisting of<br />

moneylenders, rel<strong>at</strong>ives, big farmers <strong>and</strong> traders.<br />

The committee examined the rural credit delivery system m<br />

the light of the question on how to ensure an efficient supply of<br />

institutional credit to increase the productivity of the agricultural<br />

18


sector - a dominant sector in the n<strong>at</strong>ional economy. Taking the<br />

importance of credit in achieving the targets on agricultural<br />

production into account, the committee recommended new<br />

initi<strong>at</strong>ives like St<strong>at</strong>e partnership <strong>at</strong> different <strong>levels</strong>, <strong>and</strong> co-ordin<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

between credit <strong>and</strong> other economic activities, especially processing<br />

<strong>and</strong> marketing. Increased financial support from the government to<br />

co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives <strong>and</strong> RBI, <strong>and</strong> technical support to the co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives<br />

credit structure were the other important recommend<strong>at</strong>ions.<br />

Besides, financial institutions were designed <strong>at</strong> different <strong>levels</strong> to<br />

facilit<strong>at</strong>e the credit requirement of farmers to a gre<strong>at</strong>er extent. The<br />

st<strong>at</strong>e level co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive credit institutions consisted of St<strong>at</strong>e Cooper<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

Bank, Central L<strong>and</strong> Mortgage Bank <strong>and</strong> St<strong>at</strong>e Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

Marketing Society in each St<strong>at</strong>e. The institutions of District Centr2-!<br />

Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive Bank, Primary L<strong>and</strong> Mortgage Bank <strong>and</strong> District<br />

Marketing Society were <strong>for</strong>med <strong>at</strong> the district level <strong>for</strong> better<br />

alloc<strong>at</strong>ion of agricultural credit. Primary Agricultural Credit Societies<br />

(PACSs) <strong>and</strong> Large Area Multi Purpose Societies (LAMPs) were the<br />

primary level co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives. The committee also recommended the<br />

amalgam<strong>at</strong>ion of the Imperial Bank of India into the St<strong>at</strong>e Bank of<br />

India to extend banking facilities in the countryside. In 1963, the<br />

Agricultural Re<strong>finance</strong> Corpor<strong>at</strong>ion (ARC) was established in the RBI<br />

with a view to supplement long-term resources to credit institutions.<br />

These policies heralded a new phase in agricultural credit. During<br />

this period, the share of credit to rural households provided by the<br />

financial institutions - co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives, banks, <strong>and</strong> government rose<br />

from 7.2 per cent to 29.2 per cent (K<strong>at</strong>ula <strong>and</strong> Gul<strong>at</strong>i 1992).<br />

19


Table 2.1: Distribution of Total Debt of Rural Households by<br />

Different Sources<br />

(in percenta e s)<br />

Sources 1951 1961 I 1971 I 19~<br />

Government, Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives <strong>and</strong> Banks 7. 2 17. 3 I 29.2 I 6 J. 2<br />

Rel<strong>at</strong>ives <strong>and</strong> Friends Il. 5 5. 8: 13. 8 : 9.0.<br />

Moneylenders 80. 2 69.4 ! 54.2 i 24. 3'<br />

Others l. I 7.5: 2.8: 5 5 I<br />

Total credit fRs. crores <strong>at</strong> 1971-72 prices) NA 36,100 I 37,541 I 23,361 I<br />

Notes: NA - Not aVaIlable.<br />

Source: K<strong>at</strong>ula <strong>and</strong> Gul<strong>at</strong>i (1992).<br />

A study by the RBI on the role of co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive credit in<br />

increasing farm production in 12 districts during the period 1963-64<br />

to 1965-66, however, found th<strong>at</strong>:<br />

;,. the share of credit provided by the co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives to total credit<br />

was small to moder<strong>at</strong>e in most of the districts;<br />

;,. a cnn ~;dpr~ hlp n~rt nf thp ,...,...,D,.l'1- "'~""s ....1~~P'""_ ........ ..4 +.,... ~U·l-lnl-U-U.J-U·'-"'Lj'-V-C-<br />

- - --"-- -- -~-- .r-'............ ....... ............ ........ .............. J.\. ~w~... uJ.,.. ........ L\""U LV r "'"<br />

purposes;<br />

;,. the co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive credit was found to be untimely, inadequ<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong><br />

ineffective in increasing farm production; <strong>and</strong><br />

;,. the central co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive bank <strong>and</strong> the PACSs in several st<strong>at</strong>es<br />

remained stagnant in credit growth because of growing overdues,<br />

<strong>and</strong> th<strong>at</strong> PACS were not designed to mobilise the rural savmgs,<br />

considered to be an important source of loanable funds.<br />

In July 1966, the RBI constituted an All India Rural Credit<br />

Review Committee to undertake a comprehensive revIew of<br />

agricultural credit system so th<strong>at</strong> the bottleneck could be identified<br />

<strong>and</strong> remedied. The report, published in July 1969, found th<strong>at</strong> a<br />

number of banks <strong>and</strong> societies were weak in mobilising deposits,<br />

recovering loans <strong>and</strong> management. The remedial measures<br />

suggested were rehabilit<strong>at</strong>ion of weak branches, administr<strong>at</strong>ive <strong>and</strong><br />

policy measures <strong>for</strong> checking overdues, direct financing of cultiv<strong>at</strong>ors<br />

by central banks <strong>and</strong> of societies by apex banks in areas where they<br />

were weak. The committee also suggested streamlining the lending<br />

policies <strong>and</strong> procedures of co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive institutions to make credit<br />

20


more easily accessible to the small farmers according to scales of<br />

<strong>finance</strong> needed <strong>for</strong> different crops.<br />

Notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing these ef<strong>for</strong>ts, the objective of meeting the<br />

credit needs of farmers was hardly fulfilled (D<strong>and</strong>eker <strong>and</strong> Wadia<br />

1989). The share of public sector banks in the total agricultural<br />

credit was 5.4 per cent of net bank credit in 1969 (RBI 1997-98) due<br />

to their concentr<strong>at</strong>ion in urban areas, <strong>and</strong> non-suitability of<br />

repayment period <strong>and</strong> security to their requirement (Shajahan<br />

1998).<br />

Agriculture Sector Lending as a Major Policy Instrument<br />

(1969-91)<br />

This 'Nas the early phase of the green revolution in India. The advent<br />

of new technology <strong>and</strong> the introduction of High Yielding Varieties<br />

(HYV) in 1966 resulted in a gre<strong>at</strong>er dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> improved seeds,<br />

fertilisers <strong>and</strong> increased applic<strong>at</strong>ion of irrig<strong>at</strong>ion w<strong>at</strong>er. This<br />

contributed to a substantial increase in the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit, <strong>and</strong><br />

the supply of adequ<strong>at</strong>e credit was considerably beyond the capacity<br />

of the co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives. Commercial banks were, there<strong>for</strong>e, introduced<br />

to a gre<strong>at</strong>er extent to provide agricultural credit under the policy of<br />

Social Control over banks in 1967. The entry of commercial banks in<br />

the sphere of agricultural credit was intensified with the<br />

n<strong>at</strong>ionalis<strong>at</strong>ion of 14 major commercial banks in 1969 <strong>and</strong> 6 more<br />

banks l<strong>at</strong>er.<br />

The declared objectives of the new policy, known as "social <strong>and</strong><br />

development banking" were to provide (Wiggins <strong>and</strong> Rajendran<br />

1987);<br />

21


• banking services in previously unbanked or under-banked rural<br />

areas;<br />

• substantial credit to specific activities including <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

cottage industries; <strong>and</strong><br />

• credit to certain disadvantaged groups.<br />

The Government of India <strong>and</strong> the Reserve Bank of India (RBI)<br />

issued specific directives regarding "social <strong>and</strong> development<br />

banking" from time to time. These policies included the setting of<br />

targets <strong>for</strong> the expansion of rural branches, imposing ceiling on<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>es, <strong>and</strong> setting guidelines <strong>for</strong> the sectoral alloc<strong>at</strong>ion of<br />

credit. During the early part of bank n<strong>at</strong>ionalis<strong>at</strong>ion, the N<strong>at</strong>ional<br />

Credit Council under the chairmanship of D.R. Gadgil had<br />

considered the deficiencies in the system of institutional credit <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>for</strong>mul<strong>at</strong>ed the lending policies <strong>for</strong> the future. Specific lending<br />

targets were fixed <strong>for</strong> different sectors in terms of amounts to each<br />

major bank. In this context, two major steps were taken by the RBI<br />

to encourage the priority sector lending such as provision of<br />

re<strong>finance</strong> to commercial banks, <strong>and</strong> introduction of credit guarantee<br />

scheme as a support measure of bank lending.<br />

With the establishment of Regional Rural Banks in 1975,<br />

another wing to the agricultural credit was added. RRBs were<br />

designed to be low cost institutions like co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives <strong>and</strong><br />

professionalised in their management like commercial banks. Their<br />

target group was the 'weaker sections' consisting of small <strong>and</strong><br />

marginal farmers, agricultural labourers <strong>and</strong> rural artisans, <strong>and</strong><br />

their area of oper<strong>at</strong>ion was confined to specified districts.<br />

After n<strong>at</strong>ionalis<strong>at</strong>ion, lending to priority sectors became an<br />

essential component of bank lending. During the mid-1970s, the RBI


study group recommended expansion in the scope of priority sector<br />

lending to include not only <strong>agriculture</strong> (direct <strong>and</strong> indirect), smallscale<br />

industries, <strong>and</strong> export, but also road <strong>and</strong> w<strong>at</strong>er transport<br />

oper<strong>at</strong>ors, retail traders, small business, professional <strong>and</strong> selfemployed<br />

persons <strong>and</strong> educ<strong>at</strong>ion. This definition remained<br />

unchanged until the end of 1970s. For better provisioning of credit,<br />

the RBI advised the banks to raise the proportion of credit to the<br />

priority sector to total net bank credit to 33.3 per cent by March<br />

1979. In 1980, a working group set up under the chairmanship of<br />

K.S. Krishnaswamy to review the composition of the priority sector,<br />

included weaker sections <strong>and</strong> excluded export rel<strong>at</strong>ed lending from<br />

the priority sector. A major recommend<strong>at</strong>ion of the group was th<strong>at</strong> <strong>at</strong><br />

least 50 per cent of direct farm credit should go to weaker sections<br />

including marginal farmers, small farmers <strong>and</strong> agricultural<br />

labourers, or 40 per cent of the priority sector bank credit should be<br />

given to <strong>agriculture</strong> by March 1983.<br />

The Committee to Review Arrangements <strong>for</strong> <strong>Institutional</strong> Credit<br />

<strong>for</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural Development (CRAFICARD), 1981,<br />

endorsed th<strong>at</strong> commercial banks could playa significant role in the<br />

various programmes of rural development, <strong>and</strong> suggested measures<br />

to improve the quality of lending through these banks. The N<strong>at</strong>ional<br />

Bank <strong>for</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural Development (NABARD) was,<br />

there<strong>for</strong>e, set up in 1982 by the RBI <strong>for</strong> providing all types of<br />

production <strong>and</strong> investment credit <strong>for</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> rural<br />

development. NABARD is the apex institution accredited \\'ith all<br />

m<strong>at</strong>ters concerning policy, planning <strong>and</strong> oper<strong>at</strong>ions in the field of<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> other economic activities in rural areas. Its prime<br />

role is to provide credit <strong>for</strong> the promotion of <strong>agriculture</strong>, small-scale


· industries, cottage <strong>and</strong> village industries, h<strong>and</strong>icrafts <strong>and</strong> other<br />

rural crafts <strong>and</strong> allied economic activities in rural areas with a view<br />

to promoting integr<strong>at</strong>ed rural development <strong>and</strong> securing prosperitv<br />

<strong>for</strong> the rural areas. Other functions include co-ordin<strong>at</strong>ion of rural<br />

financing activities of all institutional works <strong>at</strong> the field level <strong>and</strong><br />

maintaining liaison with the Government of India, St<strong>at</strong>e<br />

governments, RBI <strong>and</strong> other n<strong>at</strong>ional level institutions.<br />

Another RBI working group under the chairmanship of A.<br />

Ghosh was set up to review the target of priority sector lending, in<br />

general, <strong>and</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong>, in particular, with reference to the n<strong>at</strong>ure<br />

of advances. The committee suggested a separ<strong>at</strong>e target <strong>for</strong> both<br />

direct <strong>and</strong> indirect farm lending from total bank credit. The direct<br />

farm lending was fixed to reach 14 per cent of net bank credit by<br />

March-1985. By taking the increasing need of credit <strong>for</strong> farming<br />

oper<strong>at</strong>ions into account, it was recommended to raise the proportion<br />

of direct farm lending to net bank credit to 16 per cent by March<br />

1987,17 per cent by 1989 <strong>and</strong> to 18 per cent by March 1990 (Table<br />

2.2). Furthermore, this group provided a comprehensive redefinition<br />

of the "weaker sections" <strong>and</strong> suggested achieving a target of either 10<br />

per cent of net bank credit or 25 per cent of total priority sectors<br />

lending by March-1985. Besides, total priority sector lending was<br />

increased to 40 per cent of the net bank credit by 1985. The lending<br />

targets <strong>for</strong> different kinds of agricultural advances are given below in<br />

Table 2.2.


__<br />

Table 2.2: Lending Targets or Agrtcu I ture Sector. u<br />

r=-N<strong>at</strong>~;e of Advance Target P~escribed from NetlWhen Target is to be :<br />

Bank Credit (in Per cent) i Reached ___!<br />

Direct advance <strong>for</strong> 16 , March-198~~.<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> allied 17 March- 1989<br />

activities 18 March-1990<br />

-j<br />

Direct + Indirect advance 18 I<br />

<strong>for</strong> agricu Iture <strong>and</strong> allied of which direct <strong>and</strong> indirect October-1993 I<br />

activities<br />

<strong>finance</strong> target were fixed <strong>at</strong><br />

13.5 % <strong>and</strong> 4.5 %<br />

respectively<br />

Source: RBI 1987-88 <strong>and</strong> 1993-94<br />

I<br />

The Re<strong>for</strong>m Period (since 1991)<br />

Preoccup<strong>at</strong>ion to achieve quantit<strong>at</strong>ive targets, ignoring qualit<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

aspects, high cost structure of oper<strong>at</strong>ions in rural areas, <strong>and</strong><br />

mounting overdues, became thre<strong>at</strong> to the viability of financial<br />

institutions. Consequently, the policy of competitive financial svstem<br />

was adopted in provisioning agricultural credit to improve the viability<br />

of financial agencies. This phase of policy started from 1991,<br />

particularly after liberalis<strong>at</strong>ion. The policy thrust of this phase can be<br />

found in the report of the Committee on the Financial System (CFS)<br />

chaired by M. Narasimham. In its very first paragraph, the report calls<br />

<strong>for</strong> a vibrant <strong>and</strong> competitive financial system to sustain the ongoing<br />

re<strong>for</strong>m in the structural aspects of the economy. The committee<br />

suggests the use of fiscal instrument <strong>for</strong> redistributive objective r<strong>at</strong>her<br />

than the credit system. Based on this, the committee recommends<br />

th<strong>at</strong> directed credit programmes be phased out. The proposals of the<br />

committee were deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of interest r<strong>at</strong>es, changing capital<br />

adequacy norms (to compete with banks globally), <strong>and</strong> removing<br />

branch licensing policy. Besides, the committee took the view th<strong>at</strong> a<br />

new institutional structure, I.e., market driven <strong>and</strong> based on<br />

profitability be cre<strong>at</strong>ed, <strong>and</strong> th<strong>at</strong> the role played by priv<strong>at</strong>e Indian <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>for</strong>eign banks need to be enlarged. In short, the Narasimham<br />

25


Committee recommended th<strong>at</strong> banking policy be guided more by the<br />

market <strong>for</strong>ce than by regul<strong>at</strong>ions of public authority.<br />

However, the government did not favour the abolition of<br />

directed lending, delinking of the rural branches of public sector<br />

commercial banks <strong>and</strong> merging them into rural banking subsidiaries,<br />

or even the cre<strong>at</strong>ion of N<strong>at</strong>ional Rural Banks except gradual<br />

deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of lending r<strong>at</strong>e. In fact, the str<strong>at</strong>egy followed by the RBI<br />

was to keep the overall share of priority sector <strong>at</strong> 40 per cent of net<br />

bank credit, <strong>and</strong> broaden the scope of priority sector lending by public<br />

sector bank to encourage diversion from direct priority sector lending<br />

to the new areas added to this sector. The whole idea was to allow the<br />

banks to fulfil the target of priority sector, in general, flnrl 8gri('u!t'-m~,<br />

in particular, from the total advances by banks, without having to<br />

lend directly much more to those areas included in this sector in the<br />

early 1990s (Shajahan 1999).<br />

Although deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of interest r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> other measures were<br />

recommended by CFS to improve efficiency, profitability <strong>and</strong> viability<br />

of the banking sector, the committee was silent on the quality of<br />

lending to achieve the above objective. The Gupta Committee (1998)<br />

looked into the quality of credit delivered by the banking system to<br />

identify the constraints faced by the commercial banks in increasing<br />

the flow of credit, introducing new products <strong>and</strong> services, <strong>and</strong><br />

simplifying procedures to enable rural borrowers to access adequ<strong>at</strong>e<br />

<strong>and</strong> timely agricultural credit from the commercial banks.<br />

The committee emphasised on pre-sanction appraisal to assess<br />

the borrower st<strong>at</strong>us, capability <strong>for</strong> undertaking the proposed activity,<br />

26


creditworthiness <strong>and</strong> the technical viability of the proposal. The<br />

committee suggested freedom to bank branches in the selection of<br />

beneficiaries <strong>and</strong> disposal of applic<strong>at</strong>ions. To ensure quick disposal <strong>at</strong><br />

least 90 per cent of the loan applic<strong>at</strong>ions should be decided <strong>at</strong> the<br />

branch level. Short-term credit needs of the farmer should include all<br />

requirements directly or indirectly rel<strong>at</strong>ed to production, post-harvest<br />

<strong>and</strong> household expenses. Repayment capacity should be assessed on<br />

the basis of aggreg<strong>at</strong>e household income from all sources including<br />

crop production <strong>and</strong> ancillary activities. Where the l<strong>and</strong> has already<br />

been mortgaged, asking <strong>for</strong> additional coll<strong>at</strong>eral by way of guarantors<br />

should be discouraged. Commercial banks should be free to fix the<br />

r<strong>at</strong>es of interest <strong>for</strong> loans of all amounts as has already been done in<br />

the case of co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives <strong>and</strong> RRBs. To overcome the credit gap<br />

problem, the r<strong>at</strong>e of <strong>finance</strong> should be fixed <strong>for</strong> service area of each<br />

bank on the basis of local conditions r<strong>at</strong>her than <strong>for</strong> the district as a<br />

whole. Major recommend<strong>at</strong>ions of the Gupta committee accepted by<br />

the RBI are given in Box 2.1.<br />

Box 2.1: Recommend<strong>at</strong>ions of the Gupta Committee<br />

• Simplific<strong>at</strong>ion of procedures regarding loan applic<strong>at</strong>ion, agreements/<br />

documents, etc;<br />

• R<strong>at</strong>ionalis<strong>at</strong>ion of internal return of banks;<br />

• Deleg<strong>at</strong>ion of power to branch managers;<br />

• Introduction of composite cash credit limit to agricultural farmers;<br />

• Introduction of new loan products with saving component;<br />

• Cash disbursement of loans;<br />

• Dispens<strong>at</strong>ion of No Dues Certific<strong>at</strong>e; <strong>and</strong><br />

• Discretion of the bank on m<strong>at</strong>ters rel<strong>at</strong>ing to margin/ security requirements<br />

<strong>for</strong> agricultural loans above Rs 10,000.<br />

Nevertheless, with a view to making credit effective <strong>and</strong> to<br />

promote <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> rural development, the RBI continued to take<br />

new initi<strong>at</strong>ives <strong>and</strong> reorient its credit policies. Among the other major<br />

policies, Potential Linked Credit Plan (pLCP), relax<strong>at</strong>ion in re<strong>finance</strong><br />

eligibility condition to St<strong>at</strong>e Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive Banks <strong>and</strong> RRBs,<br />

27


introduction of cash credit <strong>and</strong> deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of interest r<strong>at</strong>es were<br />

prominent. The basic objective of PLCP (initi<strong>at</strong>ed by NABARD) is to<br />

explore the existing potential <strong>and</strong> work out an appropri<strong>at</strong>e credit plan<br />

through which such potential could be exploited to the maximum<br />

extent possible over a specified period of time. The credit estim<strong>at</strong>es<br />

made under this plan were expected to be revised with respect to<br />

changing economic scenario, technological improvement <strong>and</strong> cre<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

of further infrastructure <strong>and</strong> marketing facilities. To achieve gre<strong>at</strong>er<br />

efficiency in the ground level credit flow, a background paper goes to<br />

the concerned branch manager/lead bank officer (LBO) <strong>for</strong> preparing<br />

their Service Area Plans (SAPs).<br />

St<strong>at</strong>e Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive Banks <strong>and</strong> RRBs, which lost their eligibility<br />

to obtain re<strong>finance</strong> facility from NABARD on account of failure to<br />

recover <strong>at</strong> least 40 per cent of the dem<strong>and</strong> of previous years, in order<br />

not to deny fresh credit to new <strong>and</strong> non-defaulting members of cooper<strong>at</strong>ives<br />

<strong>and</strong> RRBs this condition was relaxed in December 1993.<br />

The NABARD agreed to provide re<strong>finance</strong> to the extent of their<br />

recovery (RBI 1993-94). Furthermore, with a view to ensuring<br />

adequ<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> timely flow of rural credit as to meet the composite<br />

needs of farmers, the banks were advised to extend cash credit<br />

facilities to farmers with irrig<strong>at</strong>ion facilities <strong>and</strong> also to other farmers<br />

undertaking off-farm/ allied activities, but this applied strictly to<br />

those farmers having a good track record in repayment.<br />

28


R<strong>at</strong>ionalis<strong>at</strong>ion of interest r<strong>at</strong>e (r<strong>at</strong>e to the ultim<strong>at</strong>e borrowers 7 )<br />

IS the other important aspect of policy changes in the re<strong>for</strong>m phase.<br />

The process of r<strong>at</strong>ionalis<strong>at</strong>ion of the interest r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> rural credit, in<br />

general, <strong>and</strong> agricultural credit, in particular, was initi<strong>at</strong>ed by the RBI<br />

in September 1990 based on the recommend<strong>at</strong>ions of the Narasimham<br />

Committee on deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of interest r<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong> abolition of<br />

concessional lending r<strong>at</strong>es so th<strong>at</strong> all r<strong>at</strong>es became positive in real<br />

terms. The details of this <strong>and</strong> the official reaction to this<br />

recommend<strong>at</strong>ion are summarised below:<br />

(i) The recommend<strong>at</strong>ion th<strong>at</strong> the real r<strong>at</strong>es should be positive IS<br />

accepted.<br />

(ii)<br />

The lending r<strong>at</strong>es have heen mtionalised with a reduction in the<br />

number of concessional slabs <strong>and</strong> enhancement of some r<strong>at</strong>es,<br />

thereby reducing the element of subsidy.<br />

(iii)<br />

Since there is inadequ<strong>at</strong>e margin between the cost of funds <strong>and</strong><br />

lending r<strong>at</strong>es (to cover the cost of transactions <strong>and</strong> risk), there is<br />

need <strong>for</strong> evolving a two-slab structure of lending r<strong>at</strong>es. For the<br />

slab of credit limit above Rs. 2 lakhs, the interest r<strong>at</strong>e should be<br />

freely determined by the market, <strong>and</strong> one concessional interest<br />

<strong>for</strong> the credit limit up to Rs. 2 lakhs could be 2 to 3 percentage<br />

point below the Prime Lending R<strong>at</strong>e (PLR). This may lead to some<br />

increasing in the interest r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> small loans. But the committee<br />

suggests th<strong>at</strong> wh<strong>at</strong> is important is the provision of timely <strong>and</strong><br />

adequ<strong>at</strong>e credit.<br />

1 The st<strong>at</strong>e intervention in interest r<strong>at</strong>e policies has been discussed with the<br />

in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion collected from the RBI's Report 011 Currency <strong>and</strong> FlIlance Ivarious<br />

issues). For a detailed discussion of offlcial reaction on deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of interest<br />

r<strong>at</strong>es as recommended by Narasimham Committee 1991, see, RBI 11991-92), <strong>and</strong><br />

Gadgil 1997.<br />

29


(iv) The credit co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives, Commercial Banks <strong>and</strong> RRBs have all<br />

sustained large financial losses in rural lending, mainly because<br />

of high administr<strong>at</strong>ive costs, political interference, heavy overducs<br />

<strong>and</strong> a non-viable interest structure. Given the n<strong>at</strong>ure of activity of<br />

the co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive banks, it was decided th<strong>at</strong> the co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive credit<br />

structure should be totally freed from deposit/lending r<strong>at</strong>e<br />

control so th<strong>at</strong> these r<strong>at</strong>es could settle <strong>at</strong> realistic level.<br />

(v)<br />

Accordingly, lending <strong>and</strong> deposit r<strong>at</strong>es <strong>for</strong> all co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive banks,<br />

excluding Urban Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive Banks 8 , were totally deregul<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

from October 1994 subject to a minimum lending r<strong>at</strong>e of 12 per<br />

cent. RRB lending r<strong>at</strong>es were also deregul<strong>at</strong>ed from August 1996.<br />

(vi)<br />

Lending r<strong>at</strong>es of scheduled commercial banks were freed <strong>for</strong><br />

credit limits of over Rs. 2 lakhs. The prescription of minimum<br />

lending r<strong>at</strong>e was abolished <strong>and</strong> banks were advised to obtain the<br />

approval of their respective Boards <strong>for</strong> the PLR which would be<br />

the minimum r<strong>at</strong>e charged by the banks <strong>for</strong> credit limit of over<br />

Rs. 2 lakhs, <strong>and</strong> required to apply uni<strong>for</strong>mly in all their branches.<br />

(vii) For credit limit of over Rs. 25,000 <strong>and</strong> up to Rs. 2 lakhs <strong>for</strong> all<br />

advances including term loans, a uni<strong>for</strong>m lending r<strong>at</strong>e of 13.5 per<br />

cent per annum was prescribed. Effective from October 1997,<br />

instead of a uni<strong>for</strong>m lending r<strong>at</strong>e, it was decided to charge a<br />

maximum r<strong>at</strong>e of 13.5 per cent per annum (RBI 1996-97).<br />

B<br />

From June 1995, the lending r<strong>at</strong>es of Urban Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive banks were also<br />

deregul<strong>at</strong>ed subject to a minimum of 13 per cent per annum.


Thus, there was a gradual deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of interest r<strong>at</strong>e to the<br />

ultim<strong>at</strong>e borrowers since September 1990. The deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> their likely impact have been discussed in the last<br />

section of this chapter.<br />

Movement of Directed Credit in India<br />

In India, directed credit policies have been used <strong>for</strong> promoting<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> small-scale industries following the n<strong>at</strong>ionalis<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

of commercial banks in 1969 (Kohli 1997). Subsequently, banks<br />

were directed to lend 40 per cent of their net bank credit to priority<br />

sector. Under priority sector-lending, <strong>agriculture</strong> was targeted to<br />

facilit<strong>at</strong>e the adapt<strong>at</strong>ion of new technology to increase agricultural<br />

productivity. It is also argued th<strong>at</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> was targeted beolllsf'<br />

it was a risky activity <strong>and</strong> households were credit r<strong>at</strong>ioned by the<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal sector (Swamin<strong>at</strong>han 1991; Kochar 1997). Hence, the<br />

commercial <strong>and</strong> co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive banks were directed to exp<strong>and</strong> their<br />

rural branch networks <strong>and</strong> to intensify their lending to <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

during the post n<strong>at</strong>ionalis<strong>at</strong>ion periods.<br />

However, India's directed rural credit programme was not a<br />

success in all respects (Naastepad 2001). Ramach<strong>and</strong>ran <strong>and</strong><br />

Swamin<strong>at</strong>han (2001) were also of the view th<strong>at</strong> although advances in<br />

the countryside increased substantially, such an increase was<br />

uneven, as was the case with green revolution, across regions, crops<br />

<strong>and</strong> classes. The households with an asset holding of less than Rs<br />

10,000 depended on priv<strong>at</strong>e agencies <strong>for</strong> 67 to 90 per cent of their<br />

credit needs (D<strong>and</strong>ekar <strong>and</strong> Wadia 1989). It is also found th<strong>at</strong>,<br />

although moneylenders became less important after independence<br />

due to government intervention in the agricultural credit market<br />

31


through directed credit policies, they still played an important role<br />

largely due to the poor quality of institutional credit (Rajasekhar <strong>and</strong><br />

Vyasulu 1990). Bell (1990) notes th<strong>at</strong> the RBI had exagger<strong>at</strong>ed the<br />

erosion of the moneylender's power in the unorganised credit<br />

market. This meant th<strong>at</strong> financial institutions did not help small <strong>and</strong><br />

marginal farmers, l<strong>and</strong>less labourers <strong>for</strong> whom they were primarily<br />

set up.<br />

It has been argued th<strong>at</strong> the low lending r<strong>at</strong>es set <strong>for</strong><br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> as compared to commercial <strong>and</strong> industrial r<strong>at</strong>es is one of<br />

the important factors <strong>for</strong> poor alloc<strong>at</strong>ion, <strong>and</strong> distribution of credit to<br />

this sector. The commercial banks have to cover the cost of their<br />

agricultural loan from profit arising out of other oper<strong>at</strong>ions <strong>and</strong><br />

cross-subsidise the <strong>agriculture</strong> sector (K<strong>at</strong>ula <strong>and</strong> Gul<strong>at</strong>i 1992; Rao<br />

1994; Binswanger <strong>and</strong> Kh<strong>and</strong>ker 1995). A h<strong>and</strong>ful of liter<strong>at</strong>ure on<br />

directed credit policies also support the ineffectiveness in alloc<strong>at</strong>ing 9<br />

a larger share of <strong>for</strong>mal loans to <strong>agriculture</strong>, in general, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

rural poor, in particular, because of risks, return <strong>and</strong> costs of doing<br />

so are un<strong>at</strong>tractive to <strong>for</strong>mal lenders (Lad man <strong>and</strong> Adams 1978; Fry<br />

1979; Vogel <strong>and</strong> Larson 1980).<br />

Furthermore, because of asymmetry of in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion between<br />

lender <strong>and</strong> borrowers, equilibrium credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning is an inherent<br />

fe<strong>at</strong>ure of financial market (Stiglitz <strong>and</strong> Weiss 1981; Cho 1986;<br />

Gibson <strong>and</strong> Tsakalotos 1994). Such r<strong>at</strong>ioning is inevitable in<br />

situ<strong>at</strong>ions where banks can distinguish between groups of borrowers<br />

9 It has been also argued th<strong>at</strong> oper<strong>at</strong>ions of Rural Financial Markets (RFMs) in<br />

most countries are resulting in inefficient alloc<strong>at</strong>ion of resources, causing<br />

income <strong>and</strong> asset ownership concentr<strong>at</strong>ion, allowing financial resources to flow<br />

out of low income areas <strong>and</strong>, in some cases, diverting resources out of<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> (Adams <strong>and</strong> Tommy 1974; Vogel 1977; Araujo <strong>and</strong> Me\'er 1978).<br />

"<br />

.'-


(<strong>for</strong> example, on the basis of farm/ firm Size or sector), but cannot<br />

distinguish between individual (good or bad) borrower within a<br />

group. Besides, banks cannot filter the borrowers with high risk<br />

without incurring costs. It is also difficult <strong>for</strong> the banks to use the<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>e as screening device due to adverse selection. This is due<br />

to the fact th<strong>at</strong> borrowers, willing to pay high interest r<strong>at</strong>es, may be<br />

less worried about repayment of the loan. Under these<br />

circumstances, a profit maximising bank will practice credit<br />

r<strong>at</strong>ioning <strong>and</strong> be reluctant to increase interest r<strong>at</strong>es in response to<br />

an excess dem<strong>and</strong> (Stiglitz <strong>and</strong> Weiss 1981). Consequently, high<br />

risky group borrower may be completely excluded from the market<br />

although their prospective investments offer a high-expected return.<br />

Since <strong>agriculture</strong> is a risky activity where farmers face sho~ks to<br />

their income, bankers are practising a tight credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning process,<br />

which pre-empts farmers from accessing credit (Besley 1994;<br />

Binswanger <strong>and</strong> Deininger 1997).<br />

The subsidised agricultural credit programmes <strong>and</strong> its impact<br />

on the per<strong>for</strong>mance of RFMs came under <strong>at</strong>tack lO as early as the<br />

mid-1970s (Helf<strong>and</strong> 2001). The liter<strong>at</strong>ure th<strong>at</strong> emerged in early<br />

1980s focused on issues of imperfect in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion, adverse selection,<br />

moral hazard, market failures, <strong>and</strong> interlinked transactions (Stiglitz<br />

<strong>and</strong> Weiss 1981; Bardhan 1984; Hoff <strong>and</strong> Stiglitz 1993; Besley<br />

1994). This liter<strong>at</strong>ure focused on in<strong>for</strong>mal credit in part due to the<br />

demise of cheap <strong>for</strong>mal credit programme (Helf<strong>and</strong> 2001).<br />

10 The main criticisms were alloc<strong>at</strong>ive inefficiencies, concentr<strong>at</strong>ion of income <strong>and</strong><br />

wealth in a particular class of people, <strong>and</strong> failing to achieve their objectives of<br />

promoting agricultural modernis<strong>at</strong>ion. increasing agricultural output <strong>and</strong><br />

redistribution of income in favour of the rural poor. For more details, see, Shaw<br />

1973; Donald 1976; Adams <strong>and</strong> Graham 1981.<br />

33


In the directed credit policies, importance was given to th('<br />

outreach by neglecting the quality <strong>and</strong> cost of lending. Because of<br />

this, the <strong>for</strong>mal banking system began to face the problems of higher<br />

transaction costs (due to lending small amounts to a large number of<br />

borrowers). The disbursal of loans without assessing the feasibility,<br />

viability, <strong>and</strong> entrepreneurial experience of borrowers led the banks<br />

to incur losses due to the widespread problem of fungibility <strong>and</strong> poor<br />

repayment of the loan. Hence, notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing the empirical support<br />

<strong>for</strong> the positive growth effects of directed credit in both <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> small-scale industry, the focus of India's recent financial<br />

re<strong>for</strong>ms is on the phasing-out of its directed credit programme<br />

(Shajahan 1999; Naastepad 2001).<br />

The financial re<strong>for</strong>m (Committee on the Financial System<br />

1991) was primarily concerned with the decline in productivity <strong>and</strong><br />

efficiency of the banking sector. The report points out th<strong>at</strong> directed<br />

credit had neg<strong>at</strong>ive effects on the income of banks through<br />

concessional interest r<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong> high administr<strong>at</strong>ive costs of such<br />

loans. To improve efficiency, the Committee recommended reducing<br />

directed credit from the prevailing 40 per cent to 10 per cent of net<br />

bank credit over a three-year period. Because of strong opposition<br />

from farmers <strong>and</strong> small-scale industry <strong>and</strong> political lobby, the<br />

government has not officially accepted this recommend<strong>at</strong>ion.<br />

Nevertheless, the priority sector lending was reduced to 33 per cent<br />

of gross bank credit (Naastepad 2001). It is also argued th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

per<strong>for</strong>mance of the directed credit programme has been improved<br />

significantly by reducing interest r<strong>at</strong>e subsidies (on loans over Rs.<br />

200,000) <strong>and</strong> giving gre<strong>at</strong>er emphasis on lending along commercial<br />

lines to reduce non-per<strong>for</strong>ming loans (Sarkar <strong>and</strong> Agrawal 1997).


. \ l_<br />

There<strong>for</strong>e, it can be argued th<strong>at</strong> the policy to increase the efficiency<br />

of banking sector may have direct as well as indirect effect on the<br />

rural economy. In other words, how far the efficiency of the banking<br />

sector has been taken into account to increase the credit flow to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>, employment, <strong>and</strong> income distribution needs to be<br />

examined<br />

Importantly, despite increasing consensus to extend credit<br />

facility to <strong>agriculture</strong>, in general, <strong>and</strong> small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmer, in<br />

particular, banks were unable to fund those activities with high social<br />

return or those c<strong>at</strong>egories of credit-worthy borrowers who had been<br />

marginalised in credit markets (Stiglitz 1994). It is also argued th<strong>at</strong><br />

the unusually low setting of interest r<strong>at</strong>es on credit-saving (much<br />

lower than the opportunity cost of capital) limited the access of small<br />

<strong>and</strong> marginal farmers to institutional credit since these low r<strong>at</strong>es lead<br />

the lenders to select only borrowers with excellent credit r<strong>at</strong>ings<br />

(Kamajou 1980). So, given these problems wh<strong>at</strong> makes certain<br />

households to access institutional credit <strong>and</strong> others do not? This issue<br />

will be discussed 111 detail <strong>at</strong> the household level analysis.<br />

Nevertheless, the ineffectiveness of directed agricultural credit system<br />

in terms of alloc<strong>at</strong>ion have been discussed in gre<strong>at</strong>er detail more<br />

deeply in the subsequent section with respect to interest r<strong>at</strong>e policy,<br />

cost of lending, <strong>and</strong> the process of credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning.<br />

Subsidised Interest R<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> Its Impact on Agricultural Credit<br />

Flow<br />

Interest r<strong>at</strong>e plays an important role in determining the supph'<br />

of agricultural credit. In general, the interest r<strong>at</strong>e on agricultural loans<br />

is kept low to promote agricultural growth <strong>and</strong> to assist the rural poor<br />

in developing countries. Several decades of experience on the impact<br />

35


of low interest r<strong>at</strong>es indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> cheap loans did not appear to have<br />

either increased agricultural output or reached the rural poor l I<br />

(Adams <strong>and</strong> Vogel 1986). Gonzalez-Vega (1984), <strong>and</strong> Ladmarr <strong>and</strong><br />

Tinnermeier (1981) argue th<strong>at</strong> subsidised interest r<strong>at</strong>es are the major<br />

contributing factors <strong>for</strong> fungibility on the part of borrowers <strong>and</strong> credit<br />

diversion on the part of lenders, low lender revenue <strong>and</strong> pohtical<br />

intervention into the credit market.<br />

Thus, if the interest income is gre<strong>at</strong>er than or <strong>at</strong> least equal to<br />

the cost of lending (break-even condition 12), this may positively<br />

influence the financial institutions ll1 increasing the supply of<br />

agricultural credit. However, default r<strong>at</strong>e plays an important role ll1<br />

determining the break-even level of interest r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> a financial<br />

11 The question of why <strong>for</strong>mal credit is used to a lesser extent by small <strong>and</strong> potential<br />

borrowers is adequ<strong>at</strong>ely explained in the liter<strong>at</strong>ure. McKinon (1973) <strong>and</strong> Shaw<br />

(1973) are of the view th<strong>at</strong> the ceilings on interest r<strong>at</strong>es do not permit banks to<br />

incorpor<strong>at</strong>e the additional administr<strong>at</strong>ive costs th<strong>at</strong> are involved in advancing<br />

small loans <strong>and</strong> supervise them. The <strong>for</strong>mal lenders basically r<strong>at</strong>ion credit to the<br />

small borrowers in order to reduce their transaction costs (Gonzalez-Vaga 1984;<br />

Anderson <strong>and</strong> Khamb<strong>at</strong>a 1985) which are high <strong>for</strong> servicing small borrowers.<br />

Consequently, banks advance loans to those who offer lower risk <strong>and</strong> better<br />

security. Sarap (1991) is of the view th<strong>at</strong> a typical borrower in unorganised credit<br />

market has no access to organised credit market because of the coll<strong>at</strong>eral he<br />

offers is not acceptable in the organised credit market. Credit is invariably<br />

r<strong>at</strong>ioned in terms of the ability to offer coll<strong>at</strong>eral (Rudra 1982; Binswanger <strong>and</strong><br />

Sillers 1983). Lele (1981) is of the view th<strong>at</strong> credit worthiness criterion adopted by<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal credit institutions is alien<strong>at</strong>ing small farmers from borrowing.<br />

12 (Income from loan portfolio)" (Cost of lending)<br />

(1 + r) I (I - PJ) XJ" I (I + i + aJ) XJ ----------------- (*)<br />

where X, ~ size of each loan<br />

i ~ interest paid per unit of principal on borrowing <strong>and</strong> deposits<br />

a ~ I a, X, I L X,<br />

a J ~ administr<strong>at</strong>ive cost per unit of capital<br />

r ~ lending interest r<strong>at</strong>e<br />

p ~ I P, X, I I X, (expected default r<strong>at</strong>e on loan)<br />

PJ ~ per unit loss of principal due to default on a loan size <strong>for</strong> Xj<br />

B,· substituting the above values in the equ<strong>at</strong>ion (') we can obtain<br />

r" (i +a + p) I (l - p) ----------------- (break-even condition of intere,t r<strong>at</strong>e)<br />

For more details, see, Anderson <strong>and</strong> Khamb<strong>at</strong>a (1985) <strong>and</strong> Hulme <strong>and</strong> Mosel\<br />

(1996).<br />

36


institution. Higher the default r<strong>at</strong>es, higher the break-even interest<br />

r<strong>at</strong>e th<strong>at</strong> has to be charged. But, given the administr<strong>at</strong>ive interest<br />

r<strong>at</strong>e, the banks cannot increase their lending r<strong>at</strong>es irrespective of the<br />

default r<strong>at</strong>e. There<strong>for</strong>e, the banks will try to bring down the breakeven<br />

condition of lending r<strong>at</strong>e to the economic criterion 13 of r<strong>at</strong>e of<br />

interest by reducing the default r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> the cost of lending. In order<br />

to reduce the default r<strong>at</strong>e, banks can adopt the process of credit<br />

r<strong>at</strong>ioning l4 . Furthermore, if there is r<strong>at</strong>ioning, there would exist an<br />

excess dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit than the size of loan sanctioned <strong>at</strong> the profit<br />

maximising r<strong>at</strong>e. Even in the absence of interest r<strong>at</strong>es restriction, as<br />

the probability of default risk is more due to imperfect in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion in<br />

the rural credit market, non-price credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning 15 is widely accepted<br />

in most of th" Lors (Gonzalez-Vega 1984). Besides, low interest r<strong>at</strong>e<br />

leads to low return <strong>and</strong> poor supervision, which may cause overdue<br />

<strong>and</strong> more risk to the financial institutions. To avoid these problems,<br />

financial institutions may prefer to concentr<strong>at</strong>e on a few selected<br />

13 The marginal efficiency of capital must be gre<strong>at</strong>er than or <strong>at</strong> least equal to the r<strong>at</strong>e<br />

of return on lending (i.e., lending r<strong>at</strong>e of interest). The economic benefit of<br />

investment on loans depends on the amount repaid by the borrowers. For more<br />

details, see, Anderson <strong>and</strong> Khamb<strong>at</strong>a (1985).<br />

14 It refers to a situ<strong>at</strong>ion where <strong>at</strong> the going r<strong>at</strong>e of interest in the credit transaction,<br />

the borrower likes to borrow more money but it is not permitted by the lender<br />

(Basu 1997; Ray 1998). Fried <strong>and</strong> Howitt (1980) are of the view th<strong>at</strong> credit<br />

r<strong>at</strong>ioning exists as a part of an equilibrium risk sharing arrangement between<br />

Formal Financial Institutions (F'Flsj <strong>and</strong> the borrower. Credit is invariably<br />

r<strong>at</strong>ioned in terms of ability to offer coll<strong>at</strong>eral (Rudra 1982; Binswanger <strong>and</strong> Sillers<br />

1983; Von Pischke et al 1983; <strong>and</strong> Sarap 1991). For a more detailed discussion<br />

on the impact of interest r<strong>at</strong>e ceiling <strong>and</strong> credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning, see, Gonzalez-Vega<br />

(1984), Anderson <strong>and</strong> Khamb<strong>at</strong>a (1985), <strong>and</strong> Basu (1997). E<strong>at</strong>on <strong>and</strong> Gersovitz<br />

(1981) have suggested a model with endogenous default costs where default leads<br />

to exclusion from the credit market. Given this. a contract is en<strong>for</strong>ceable provided<br />

th<strong>at</strong> each payment is less than the value of future access from the credit market.<br />

15 In the case of non-price credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning. the potential borrower is willing to pay<br />

the full price (i.e., non-interest term <strong>and</strong> conditions of the loan contract with<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>e charged), but the <strong>for</strong>mal financial institutions are not willing to grant<br />

the loan of the size dem<strong>and</strong>ed. For more details, see, Jafee (1971 J, <strong>and</strong> Gonzalez­<br />

Vega (1984).<br />

37


orrowers, those who have creditworthiness with excellent loan<br />

coll<strong>at</strong>eral <strong>and</strong> those who take large loans. This suggests th<strong>at</strong> a ceiling<br />

on lending r<strong>at</strong>e has two kinds of impact on the institutional credit<br />

market. The first type of impact can be observed in the flow of credit<br />

<strong>and</strong> the second one can be observed in access to credit by different<br />

c<strong>at</strong>egory borrowers.<br />

The interest r<strong>at</strong>e ceiling seems to have had similar impact in<br />

India. The provision of cheap credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> in India gives rise to<br />

two kinds of credit subsidyl6. First, the interest subsidy accrues to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> because the r<strong>at</strong>e of lending to this sector is lower<br />

compared to the other sectors of the economy. The second type of<br />

credit subsidy is the difference between the CO!lt of !lupplying credit to<br />

the agricultural sector, including defaults <strong>and</strong> r<strong>at</strong>e of interest received<br />

from outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit. Using the above conceptual framework,<br />

K<strong>at</strong>ula <strong>and</strong> Gul<strong>at</strong>i's (1992) study reveals th<strong>at</strong> concessional interest<br />

r<strong>at</strong>es autom<strong>at</strong>ically result in cross subsidis<strong>at</strong>ion. They are of the view<br />

th<strong>at</strong> of the three types of banks in India, i.e., Commercial Banks<br />

(CBs), RRBs <strong>and</strong> Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives, only CBs have the scope <strong>for</strong> crosssubsidis<strong>at</strong>ion.<br />

It happens in the case of CBs because they lend to a<br />

variety of sectors <strong>and</strong> have the possibility to lend to those activities<br />

th<strong>at</strong> earn interest of more than 16 per cent. Besides, they have also<br />

estim<strong>at</strong>ed th<strong>at</strong> during the 1980s, the total credit subsidy to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> was 7.36 per cent of the outst<strong>and</strong>ing. This implies th<strong>at</strong><br />

7.36 per cent of the total loanable funds could not come back to the<br />

banking system, <strong>and</strong> to th<strong>at</strong> extent the quantum of funds available to<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal banks came down. This is further corrobor<strong>at</strong>ed by Bishnoi's<br />

(1991) argument th<strong>at</strong> interest subsidy to priority sectors compared to<br />

16 For a detailed discussion, see, K<strong>at</strong>ula <strong>and</strong> Gul<strong>at</strong>i (1992).<br />

38


the industrial sector has been the major contributing factor <strong>for</strong> lower<br />

credit flow to the <strong>agriculture</strong> sector.<br />

Can financial institutions go <strong>for</strong> higher lending r<strong>at</strong>e to get a<br />

good margin out of their deployment of funds to the <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

sector? The Agricultural Credit Review Committee headed by Khusro<br />

(1989) <strong>and</strong> the Committee on Financial System (1991) had<br />

recommended enhancement of lending r<strong>at</strong>es to cover risk <strong>and</strong><br />

additional costs associ<strong>at</strong>ed with it. In this context, a study made bv<br />

Gadgil (1992, 1994) reveals th<strong>at</strong>, by <strong>and</strong> large, farmers could af<strong>for</strong>d<br />

higher interest r<strong>at</strong>es if accompanied by an improvement in the quality<br />

of lending.<br />

In theory, however, a question was raised on whether one could<br />

take higher lending r<strong>at</strong>e as the criterion of the profitability. Stiglitz<br />

<strong>and</strong> Weiss (1981) argue th<strong>at</strong> increasing interest r<strong>at</strong>es or increasing<br />

coll<strong>at</strong>eral requirements could increase the riskiness of the bank's loan<br />

portfolio, either by discouraging safer investors or by inducing<br />

borrowers to invest in a riskier projects, <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e, could decrease<br />

the bank's profit. This implies th<strong>at</strong> the bank may incur more loss with<br />

the increased lending r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> it may adversely affect the viability of<br />

the system. It may also happen th<strong>at</strong> many good borrowers may move<br />

out from the <strong>for</strong>mal credit market with increasing lending r<strong>at</strong>e.<br />

Making a similar point on viability, Basu (1997) notes th<strong>at</strong> it is the<br />

default risk, r<strong>at</strong>her than the ceiling on interest r<strong>at</strong>e, which IS the<br />

major contributing factor of non-profitability <strong>and</strong> non-viability.<br />

Ceiling on Interest R<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong> Access to <strong>Institutional</strong> Credit<br />

Gonzalez-Vega (1984) has developed a conceptual framework on credit<br />

r<strong>at</strong>ioning <strong>and</strong> their impact on access to institutional credit with the<br />

39


help of non-price credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning by assuming a binding ceiling on<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>e is imposed on the banks. The Iron Law of Interest R<strong>at</strong>e<br />

Restrictiolls st<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong>, when interest r<strong>at</strong>e ceiling becomes more<br />

restrictive, the size of the loan granted to non-r<strong>at</strong>ioned borro\\·er<br />

classes increases, while the size of loan granted to the r<strong>at</strong>ioned<br />

borrower classes diminishes (Gonzalez-Vega 1984). The Iron Law of<br />

Interest R<strong>at</strong>e Restriction assumes th<strong>at</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit is inversely<br />

rel<strong>at</strong>ed to the real r<strong>at</strong>e of interest <strong>and</strong> the lender's marginal cost<br />

increases with loan size (Figure 2.1).<br />

Figure 2.1 shows th<strong>at</strong> when r<strong>at</strong>ioning IS taking place, the<br />

marginal cost of the loan becomes equal to the ceiling interest r<strong>at</strong>e.<br />

Hence, depending on the rel<strong>at</strong>ive level of ceiling with respect to<br />

marginal cost of lending, some or all of the borrowers may be<br />

subjected to non-price credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning. Figure 2.1 also shows th<strong>at</strong>, <strong>for</strong><br />

the r<strong>at</strong>ioned borrower, credit is available along the lender's marginal<br />

cost curve whereas <strong>for</strong> non-r<strong>at</strong>ioned borrower along with his credit<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> curve.<br />

Figure 2.1: R<strong>at</strong>ioning Behaviour oftbe Lender<br />

r<br />

(Non-r<strong>at</strong>ioned borrower)<br />

MC2<br />

r<br />

r*<br />

MC.<br />

(R<strong>at</strong>ioned borrower)<br />

Credit) D,<br />

Source: Gonzalez-Vega (1984)<br />

D, (Credit)<br />

·HI


From the above theoretical model, one can see th<strong>at</strong> ceiling on<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> cost of lending have serious implic<strong>at</strong>ion on access to<br />

institutional credit. Given the risks <strong>and</strong> transaction costs associ<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

with lending, most of the <strong>for</strong>mal financial institutions try to optimise<br />

the loan size to each class of borrowers by credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning devices.<br />

Thus, when credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning takes place, two things can happen. First,<br />

financial institutions may concentr<strong>at</strong>e on a select few, those who have<br />

credit worthiness with excellent loan coll<strong>at</strong>eral. Second, since access<br />

to credit <strong>and</strong> loan sizes are highly correl<strong>at</strong>ed with income level <strong>and</strong><br />

assets, large farmers <strong>and</strong> the well-to-do benefit most from the cheap<br />

credit (Lipton 1976; Lele 1981; Adams <strong>and</strong> Vogel 1986; Braverman<br />

<strong>and</strong> Guasch 1986).<br />

The above discussion focuses on the poor access to<br />

institutional credit by some c<strong>at</strong>egory of agricultural borrowers from<br />

the supply side point of view. However, the analysis of availability <strong>and</strong><br />

access to institutional credit by the borrower may not be complete<br />

without taking into account the dem<strong>and</strong> side problems. It is often<br />

argued th<strong>at</strong> small <strong>and</strong> medium borrowers are indifferent as to whether<br />

to seek a <strong>for</strong>mal or in<strong>for</strong>mal loan because they feel th<strong>at</strong> their total cost<br />

of acquiring a loan from either source are similar (Adams <strong>and</strong> Nehman<br />

1979). In this context, it is essential to focus the factors, which<br />

influence the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> institutional credit.<br />

Borrowing Costs <strong>and</strong> Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> Credit<br />

The liter<strong>at</strong>ure on <strong>for</strong>mal credit contains several explan<strong>at</strong>ions <strong>for</strong> the<br />

limited dem<strong>and</strong> of <strong>for</strong>mal credit by small <strong>and</strong> potential borrowers. The<br />

liter<strong>at</strong>ure focuses th<strong>at</strong> most poor do not seek <strong>for</strong>mal credit due to lack<br />

of profitable investment opportunities <strong>and</strong> poor idea of credit use.<br />

41


42<br />

Schrieder (2000) argues th<strong>at</strong> many poor do not approach <strong>for</strong> credit<br />

from institutional credit agencies as they value the risk associ<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

with indebtedness to be higher than the possible return on<br />

investment. The other studies (Adams <strong>and</strong> Nehman 1979; Aron 1981;<br />

Timberg <strong>and</strong> Aiyar 1984; Sarap 1990) focus on borrowing costsl' <strong>and</strong><br />

borrower's behaviour on dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit. They argue th<strong>at</strong> higher<br />

borrowing costs incurred by small potential borrowers as compared to<br />

large borrowers discourage them to approach the <strong>for</strong>mal credit<br />

institutions.<br />

Ladman (1984) provides a theoretical framework on dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

credit based on the rel<strong>at</strong>ionship between average borrowing costs<br />

(ABC) <strong>and</strong> average revenue (AR) of debt <strong>finance</strong>d invest.!nent. Both AR<br />

<strong>and</strong> ABC incurred by the borrower represent revenues <strong>and</strong> borrowing<br />

costs divided by the size of the loan (Ll utilised <strong>for</strong> a particular<br />

purpose. He explains th<strong>at</strong>, with a given set of technology, the farmer,<br />

who relies upon credit, derives dem<strong>and</strong> schedule of loan from the<br />

value of marginal product by using successive loan units. It implies<br />

th<strong>at</strong>,<br />

BC = Total fixed transaction costs (Tl) + Other transaction costs<br />

(T2) <strong>and</strong> thus, ABC = (TI + T2)/ L<br />

Tl represents the amount of outlay the farmer must make in applying<br />

<strong>for</strong> a loan. The payment <strong>for</strong> applic<strong>at</strong>ion fees, service fees, documents<br />

<strong>and</strong> other paperwork are examples ofT\. The cost involved in payment<br />

<strong>for</strong> commission <strong>and</strong> bribe to offlcer / technician/ bank staff, leader or<br />

17 To obtain a loan a farmer has to go through the procedures th<strong>at</strong> are required by<br />

the lender's credit delivery system, which result in borrowing costs. The<br />

borrowing costs (Be) by the prospective borrower may include nominal interest<br />

payments made to the lender, additional loan transaction costs, <strong>and</strong> the changes<br />

in the purchasing power of the money over the loan period. For more details, see,<br />

Adams <strong>and</strong> Nehman (1979).


middleman <strong>for</strong> negoti<strong>at</strong>ion, travel to <strong>and</strong> from the financial institution<br />

<strong>and</strong> the opportunity cost of time involved are examples of T2.<br />

Since loan procedures <strong>and</strong> paperwork are independent, the<br />

average fixed cost declines with loan size. The borrowing cost also<br />

depends on the frequency of meeting bank staff, in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion of<br />

borrower's st<strong>at</strong>us on efftciency of funds investment, credit worthiness<br />

<strong>and</strong> the number of times th<strong>at</strong> a farm household obtained loan from<br />

the institutional sector. For large <strong>and</strong> experienced borrowers, the<br />

transaction costs decline. These loan transaction costs appear to be<br />

much less important <strong>for</strong> large size borrowers. However, loan<br />

transaction costs appear to make up a very large part of borrowing<br />

costs <strong>for</strong> many small <strong>and</strong> medium si7.p horrowprs (Adl'lms <strong>and</strong> Nphman<br />

01 - •• - - - ,- - - ----- - --<br />

1979). Since total borrowing cost is the summ<strong>at</strong>ion of interest<br />

payment (r) <strong>and</strong> transaction cost, ABC declines with respect to the size<br />

of loan.<br />

Let us assume th<strong>at</strong> the borrower is a profit (n) maxlmlser <strong>and</strong><br />

thus seeks a loan if he expects n > 0 i.e. AR > ABC. Thus, the borrower<br />

would borrow until the point where marginal cost of borrowing<br />

(additional interest payment) is equal to marginal value product (MVP)<br />

from additional resources purchased with borrowed funds (Figure<br />

2.2). Given the interest r<strong>at</strong>es r, the vertical distance between r<strong>and</strong><br />

ABC represent transaction cost <strong>for</strong> any size of loan. Thus, larger the<br />

borrower's transaction cost, the higher will be the average borrowing<br />

cost <strong>and</strong> vice-versa <strong>for</strong> any given interest r<strong>at</strong>e.<br />

43


Figure 2.2: Borrowing Costs <strong>and</strong> Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> Credit<br />

ABC<br />

AR/ABC/D/MVP<br />

IT<br />

AR<br />

r<br />

TC<br />

D/MVP<br />

Source: Ladman (1984)<br />

Tl L* Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> Credit<br />

From the above analysis, one can say th<strong>at</strong>, gIVen the binding<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>e, it is the bcrrc\ver~s transnction cost, v,thich determines<br />

the level of dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit. Figure 2.2 shows th<strong>at</strong> borrowing<br />

threshold (TJ) is the point where ABC = AR. Below this amount there<br />

will be no dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit because ABC> AR. If the borrower's TC<br />

exceeds a certain level of their expect<strong>at</strong>ion, they may not approach <strong>for</strong><br />

institutional credit. It is observed th<strong>at</strong> not all applicants <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

credit receive a loan. The expected borrowing costs of a new <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

applicant may be increased by their rejection possibility. These<br />

rejection costs may be quite important if the probability of getting a<br />

new <strong>for</strong>mal loan is rel<strong>at</strong>ively low. Besides, many are of the view th<strong>at</strong><br />

differential borrowing cost strongly affects the willingness of the rural<br />

poor to seek loan from the <strong>for</strong>mal sector.<br />

Conclnding Remarks<br />

Realising the importance of credit In terms of changing the<br />

composition <strong>and</strong> distribution of production In favour of deficit<br />

producers, shifting rural borrowing from in<strong>for</strong>mal to <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

institutions, <strong>and</strong> increasing the use of improved variety inputs, the<br />

44


supply-led approach has been adopted m the pro\'lSlOnmg of<br />

agricultural credit in India. It is also realised th<strong>at</strong> both revealed <strong>and</strong><br />

potential dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit exceeds the supply. Based on these<br />

consider<strong>at</strong>ions, banks were directed to exp<strong>and</strong> the share of net bank<br />

credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector. In the directed credit policy, importance<br />

was given to the outreach by neglecting the quality <strong>and</strong> cost of<br />

lending. The high cost structure of oper<strong>at</strong>ions in rural areas with low<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>e was an important factor <strong>for</strong> the failure of directed credit<br />

system. When the supply-led approach started to thre<strong>at</strong>en the viability<br />

of financial institutions, the policy thrust since 1990s shifted to make<br />

agricultural credit a viable activity. In this phase of agricultural credit<br />

policy, importance was given to achieving quantit<strong>at</strong>ive target without<br />

neglecting the viability of the. financial institutions. Thus, the<br />

assumption of cross-subsidis<strong>at</strong>ion of agricultural credit was relaxed<br />

<strong>and</strong> the lending r<strong>at</strong>e to the ultim<strong>at</strong>e borrowers was r<strong>at</strong>ionalised in<br />

terms of reduction In the number of concessional slabs <strong>and</strong><br />

enhancement of some r<strong>at</strong>es. One could, there<strong>for</strong>e, expect th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of interest r<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong> improved quality of lending might<br />

have helped the <strong>for</strong>mal agencies to get more profit in agricultural<br />

lending, <strong>and</strong> enhanced the proportion of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> to the<br />

total net bank credit. In this context, it is necessary to discuss the<br />

likely impact of interest r<strong>at</strong>e policy in the provisioning of agricultural<br />

credit.<br />

(al Except the Differential R<strong>at</strong>e of Interest Scheme oper<strong>at</strong>ed by the<br />

commercial banks <strong>and</strong> RRBs, identical r<strong>at</strong>es are prescribed <strong>for</strong> all<br />

sectors of the economy including <strong>agriculture</strong>, which vary directly<br />

with the size of loan <strong>and</strong> there are only three size slabs18 now. The<br />

18 First slab covers the credit limit up to Rs.25, 000. The second <strong>and</strong> third slabs<br />

cover above Rs.25, 000 <strong>and</strong> up to Rs.2 lakhs, <strong>and</strong> above Rs.2 lakhs of loan<br />

respectively.


<strong>at</strong>es are also identical <strong>for</strong> short <strong>and</strong> long-term loans <strong>for</strong> a given<br />

size. However, with the freedom given to rural co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive banks<br />

since October 1994 <strong>and</strong> to RRBs since August 1996 to determine<br />

their own lending r<strong>at</strong>es <strong>for</strong> all the slabs, the uni<strong>for</strong>mity of lending<br />

r<strong>at</strong>es to ultim<strong>at</strong>e borrowers has probably vanished.<br />

(b) Since all financial institutions induding commercial banks have<br />

been given freedom to determine the lending r<strong>at</strong>es <strong>for</strong> loans above<br />

Rs. 2 lakhs, different institutions may have <strong>for</strong>mul<strong>at</strong>ed different<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>es on these loans.<br />

(c) If the lending costs (sum of financial, transaction <strong>and</strong> risk cost) of<br />

rural credit institutions [as estim<strong>at</strong>ed by the Agricultural Credit<br />

Review Committee (ACRC) <strong>for</strong> the period 1983-84 through 1985-86 J<br />

are compared with the lending r<strong>at</strong>es, the presently prescribed r<strong>at</strong>e<br />

<strong>for</strong> CBs on loans up to Rs.2 lakhs is inadequ<strong>at</strong>e to cover the costs<br />

of lending l9 . Since the maximum prescribed lending r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> CB is<br />

13.5 per cent per annum <strong>for</strong> the credit limit of up to Rs.2 lakhs, it<br />

is not possible to increase, the lending r<strong>at</strong>e to cover the costs. Thus,<br />

the CBs have the following two options. First, they may neglect the<br />

borrower who dem<strong>and</strong>s agricultural loan up to the limit of Rs.2<br />

lakhs; second, they have to cross-subsidise this segment of<br />

agricultural borrowers. It may also be possible th<strong>at</strong> in order to<br />

minimise the extent of cross-subsidy, CBs may be concentr<strong>at</strong>ing on<br />

a particular c<strong>at</strong>egory of agricultural borrowers to achieve the<br />

lending target given to them. Commercial banks may also be<br />

moving towards a higher profit-oriented portfolio through diversion<br />

19 For CBs, the cost of lending was 14.48 per cent per annum, whereas <strong>for</strong> Cooper<strong>at</strong>ives<br />

<strong>and</strong> RRB it was 16.30 per cent <strong>and</strong> 15.70 per cent, respectively.<br />

46


of funds from sectors with lower returns to those having higher<br />

returns.<br />

(d) In the case of RRBs <strong>and</strong> co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive banks, as the lending r<strong>at</strong>es<br />

have been totally deregul<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>for</strong> all slabs of credit limit, it is up to<br />

them to raise the lending r<strong>at</strong>e suitably to meet the cost of lending.<br />

However, the increasing lending r<strong>at</strong>e of RRBs <strong>and</strong> co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

banks may induce their borrower to turn to CBs. Even if such a<br />

shift in dem<strong>and</strong> takes place <strong>for</strong> the loan amount of up to Rs 2<br />

lakhs, the CBs are unlikely to extend their credit facility to such<br />

borrowers. Even if CBs extend credit facility, they may not go<br />

beyond the prescribed level of 18 per cent of net bank credit.<br />

There<strong>for</strong>e, it is important to examine th~ rli!"trihlJtion p<strong>at</strong>tern of<br />

agricultural credit by CBs <strong>for</strong> below <strong>and</strong> above the credit limits of<br />

Rs 2 lakhs.<br />

Since financial institutions are not allowed to charge less than<br />

12 per cent of annual r<strong>at</strong>es on farm <strong>and</strong> non-farm loans, it is not the<br />

floor r<strong>at</strong>e but the ceiling r<strong>at</strong>e th<strong>at</strong> has been deregul<strong>at</strong>ed. In this<br />

context, the following questions arise. Does credit subsidy due to<br />

concessionary interest r<strong>at</strong>e adversely affect the credit flow to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>? Can increasing lending r<strong>at</strong>e be a solution to reduce the<br />

r<strong>at</strong>e of credit subsidy? Wh<strong>at</strong> is the interest r<strong>at</strong>e elasticity on the<br />

supply of agricultural credit? These questions have been discussed in<br />

the third chapter.<br />

The introduction of the PLCP is likely to be helpful in removing<br />

:he ground level problems on credit flow <strong>and</strong> bridge the gap between<br />

.arget <strong>and</strong> achievement of credit to the priority sectors. The policy of<br />

47


e<strong>finance</strong> facility by NABARD might have helped to restructure the<br />

lending activity of CBs <strong>and</strong> RRBs to different sectors including<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>. Importantly, these policies may be helping CBs <strong>and</strong> RRBs<br />

to achieve their lending target given <strong>for</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> sector.<br />

Nevertheless, setting of lending targets <strong>for</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> might have<br />

resulted in a positive impact on the supply of credit to hitherto<br />

neglected sector by giving ample access <strong>for</strong> marginal <strong>and</strong> small<br />

farmers to institutional credit. In the context of these policy changes<br />

<strong>and</strong> recommend<strong>at</strong>ions made by both Narashimham <strong>and</strong> Gupta<br />

committees, the extent to which the <strong>for</strong>mal banking system has<br />

improved the access to agricultural credit is to be examined. This<br />

issue is taken up <strong>for</strong> discussion in the following chapters.<br />

48


Chapter 3<br />

CREDIT FLOW TO AGRICULTURE: TRENDS AND<br />

CONTRIBUTING FACTORS AT ALL-INDIA LEVEL<br />

Introduction<br />

The administered alloc<strong>at</strong>ion of credit to priority sectors <strong>at</strong><br />

concessional interest r<strong>at</strong>es is an important policy dimension of<br />

directed credit programmes. The r<strong>at</strong>ionale of this policy lies in the fact<br />

th<strong>at</strong>, without government interference through directed credit<br />

programmes, banks do not fund to those activities with high social<br />

return or those c<strong>at</strong>egories of credit-worthy people who are<br />

marginalised in the credit market (Stiglitz 1994). The directed credit<br />

policies in India have been used <strong>for</strong> promoting <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> smallscale<br />

industry. Agriculture has been targeted because it is a risky<br />

activity <strong>and</strong> households are credit r<strong>at</strong>ioned by the <strong>for</strong>mal sector<br />

(Swamin<strong>at</strong>han 1991; Kochar 1997). It is also felt th<strong>at</strong> the availability<br />

of concessional credit could help the farmer to adopt new technology,<br />

encourage investment on machinery <strong>and</strong> irrig<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> augment the<br />

use of quality inputs to increase agricultural productivity. Thus,<br />

commercial <strong>and</strong> co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive banks were directed to exp<strong>and</strong> their<br />

rural branch networks <strong>and</strong> intensify their lending to <strong>agriculture</strong>.<br />

After the n<strong>at</strong>ionalis<strong>at</strong>ion, lending to priority sectors became an<br />

essential component of bank lending. By taking the increasing credit<br />

needs <strong>for</strong> farming oper<strong>at</strong>ions into account, specific lending targets<br />

were fixed <strong>for</strong> each major bank. Ultim<strong>at</strong>ely, it was recommended to<br />

raise the proportion of direct farm lending to 18 per cent of net bank<br />

credit by March 1990. However, India's rural directed credit<br />

programme has not been a success, specifically in terms of alloc<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

of resources, cost-effectiveness <strong>and</strong> access to credit <strong>for</strong> different<br />

49


c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers due to the following: First, the agricultural<br />

lending r<strong>at</strong>es set by the government were lower than commercial <strong>and</strong><br />

industrial r<strong>at</strong>es, <strong>and</strong> hence, commercial banks could not cover the<br />

cost of their agricultural loan from profit ansmg from other<br />

oper<strong>at</strong>ions. This led to cross-subsidis<strong>at</strong>ion of the agricultural<br />

oper<strong>at</strong>ions (K<strong>at</strong>ula <strong>and</strong> Gul<strong>at</strong>i 1992; Rao 1994; Binswanger <strong>and</strong><br />

Kh<strong>and</strong>ker 1995). Second, the preoccup<strong>at</strong>ion to achieve quantit<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

targets, ignoring qualit<strong>at</strong>ive aspects <strong>and</strong> mounting overdues, became a<br />

thre<strong>at</strong> to the viability of financial institutions. Third, the disbursal of<br />

loans without assessing the feasibility, viability <strong>and</strong> entrepreneurial<br />

experience of borrowers (Rajasekhar <strong>and</strong> Vyasulu 1993) led the banks<br />

to incur losses due to the widespread problem of fungibility <strong>and</strong> poor<br />

repayment of the loan<br />

The effectiveness of directed credit programmes in stimul<strong>at</strong>ing<br />

investment, raising growth <strong>and</strong> reducing poverty was often deb<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

(Naastepad 2001). It is also argued th<strong>at</strong> directed credit was inferior to<br />

a market-based alloc<strong>at</strong>ion of resources in achieving growth <strong>and</strong><br />

redistributive objectives (World Bank 1989; Odedokun 1996; Varon et<br />

al. 1998). Hence, notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing the empirical support <strong>for</strong> the<br />

positive growth effects of directed credit in both <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> smallscale<br />

industry, the focus of India's recent financial re<strong>for</strong>ms has been<br />

on the phasing-out of its directed credit programmes (Shajahan 1999;<br />

Naastepad 2001). As explained by the Report of the Narasimham<br />

Committee on the Financial System (1991), the financial re<strong>for</strong>ms were<br />

primarily concerned with the decline in productivity <strong>and</strong> efficiency of<br />

the banking sector. The report points out th<strong>at</strong> the directed credit had<br />

neg<strong>at</strong>ive effects on the income of banks through concessional interest<br />

r<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong> high administr<strong>at</strong>ive costs of such loans. To improve the<br />

50


efficiency, the Committee recommended reducing the directed credit<br />

from the prevailing 40 per cent to 10 per cent of net bank credit over a<br />

three-year period. Due to strong opposition from fanners <strong>and</strong> smallscale<br />

industry <strong>and</strong> political lobby, the government did not officially<br />

accepted this recommend<strong>at</strong>ion. In fact, the RBI has been following the<br />

str<strong>at</strong>egy of keeping the overall share of priority sector <strong>at</strong> 40 per cent of<br />

net bank credit, <strong>and</strong> broadening the scope of priority sector lending to<br />

encourage diversion <strong>for</strong>m it to the new areas added to this sector. In<br />

other words, importance was given to achieve the same quantit<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

target without neglecting the viability of the financial institutions.<br />

Thus, assumption of cross-subsidis<strong>at</strong>ion of agricultural credit was<br />

relaxed <strong>and</strong> the lending r<strong>at</strong>e to the ultim<strong>at</strong>e borrowers was<br />

r<strong>at</strong>ionalised in terms of reduction in the number of c:oncessiona.l slabs<br />

<strong>and</strong> the enhancement of some r<strong>at</strong>es. The other important<br />

recommend<strong>at</strong>ions include the abolition of branch licensing, closing<br />

down of loss making bank branches, gradual reduction of Cash<br />

Reserve R<strong>at</strong>io (CRR) <strong>and</strong> St<strong>at</strong>utory Liquidity R<strong>at</strong>io (SLR).<br />

One can, there<strong>for</strong>e, expect the following positive as well as<br />

neg<strong>at</strong>ive influences of banking sector re<strong>for</strong>ms on the credit flow to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>.<br />

1. Deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of interest r<strong>at</strong>e may have helped the <strong>for</strong>mal agencies<br />

to enhance the proportion of disbursement to agricultural sector in<br />

the overall net bank credit.<br />

2. Widening scope of priority sector may have resulted in the gre<strong>at</strong>er<br />

availability of credit to priority sector, in general, <strong>and</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

sector, in particular.<br />

3. Increasing the availability of funds to the banks as a result of<br />

reduced CRR <strong>and</strong> SLR may have a positive impact on the credit<br />

flow to <strong>agriculture</strong>.<br />

51


4. Since most of the loss-making bank branches during the prere<strong>for</strong>m<br />

period were loc<strong>at</strong>ed in rural areas. the closure of bank<br />

branches may lead to reduced supply of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong>.<br />

5. The recommend<strong>at</strong>ion of the Gupta Committee th<strong>at</strong> the quality of<br />

lending is to be improved may provide ample access to institutional<br />

credit by marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers.<br />

The above raises the following questions. Does the banking sector<br />

re<strong>for</strong>ms improve the share of net bank credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector?<br />

Does profit-oriented lending norms persuade commercial banks to<br />

neglect <strong>agriculture</strong> sector? Does credit subsidy reduce the supply of<br />

agricultural credit? Can increasing lending r<strong>at</strong>e be a means to reduce<br />

the r<strong>at</strong>e of credit subsidy? Wh<strong>at</strong> is the interest r<strong>at</strong>e elasticity on the<br />

supply of agricultural credit? Wh<strong>at</strong> is the impact of the closure of<br />

rural bank branches on the provision of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong>? Does<br />

the expansion of the scope of <strong>agriculture</strong> sector bank-lending result in<br />

the gre<strong>at</strong>er availability of credit?<br />

This chapter addresses these questions by analysing the d<strong>at</strong>a<br />

collected from the Report on Currency <strong>and</strong> Finance <strong>and</strong> Banking<br />

St<strong>at</strong>istics on the total outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit provided by the Scheduled<br />

Commercial Banks (SCBs) to the <strong>agriculture</strong> sector.<br />

Credit Flow to Agriculture<br />

Soon after independence. the share of Formal Rural Banking System<br />

(FRBS) in the total credit was found to be insignificant. However. the<br />

n<strong>at</strong>ionalis<strong>at</strong>ion of banks in 1969. introduction of RRBs <strong>and</strong> priority<br />

sector lending has had the desired impact in stepping up the supply of<br />

credit to <strong>agriculture</strong>. The share of <strong>agriculture</strong> in the total credit<br />

provided by FRBS. which was only 7.1 per cent in 1969. increased to<br />

15.72 per cent of the total net bank credit by 1980.<br />

52


The total outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit disbursed by all the SeBs increased<br />

from Rs.28,391.73 crores in 1981 to Rs.460,080.68 crores by 2000.<br />

The annual growth r<strong>at</strong>e of total outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit was 15.38 per cent<br />

during this period (Table 3.1). The growth r<strong>at</strong>e during the period 1991-<br />

2000 was high as compared to th<strong>at</strong> during the period 1981- 91. One<br />

of the important contributing factors <strong>for</strong> rapid growth r<strong>at</strong>e during the<br />

re<strong>for</strong>m period was the policy decision to slash eRR <strong>and</strong> SLR to<br />

increase funds availability to the banking sector. The eRR declined<br />

from 15 per cent of dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> time liability in 1991 to 8.5 per cent<br />

in 2000, while the SLR declined from 38.5 per cent to 25 per cent<br />

during the same period. Besides, the borrowing from RBI was stepped<br />

up after 1991 to facilit<strong>at</strong>e more funds to the SeBs (RBI 2001).<br />

Was the rapid growth in the total credit the same across all the<br />

sectors? Table 3.1 shows th<strong>at</strong> the annual growth r<strong>at</strong>es of credit to<br />

professional services <strong>and</strong> personal loans, <strong>finance</strong> <strong>and</strong> others were<br />

higher during the pre-re<strong>for</strong>m period. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>at</strong><br />

which credit was disbursed to industry, trade <strong>and</strong> transport oper<strong>at</strong>ors<br />

was high during the re<strong>for</strong>m period as compared to th<strong>at</strong> in pre-re<strong>for</strong>m<br />

period. The credit disbursed to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector increased <strong>at</strong> an<br />

annual growth r<strong>at</strong>e of 11.86 per cent during the period 1981-2000.<br />

These were, however, distinct inter-period vari<strong>at</strong>ions. While the<br />

annual growth r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> the pre-re<strong>for</strong>m period was 14.77 per cent, it<br />

was only 10.90 per cent during the re<strong>for</strong>m period. Thus, the r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>at</strong><br />

which credit was disbursed to <strong>agriculture</strong> had declined <strong>at</strong> the all-India<br />

level.<br />

53


Table 3.1: Annual Average Growth R<strong>at</strong>es 2 () of Credit (%) by<br />

SCBs to Different Sectors<br />

Years ! Agricul- Indus Trans- Professional Trade Financel Others i For :<br />

I ture ·try port Services <strong>and</strong><br />

Opera- Personal<br />

I<br />

f se::~rs<br />

tors Loans<br />

,<br />

1981- 91 14.77 15.68 8.68 22.09 10.84 26.30 19.36 15.33<br />

1992 2000 10.90 16.21 11.48 20.68 15.16 24.76 16.44 16.14 i<br />

1981- 2000 11.86 15.80 7.82 21.31 13.06 26.12 17.57 15.38 I<br />

Source: Reserve Bank of India (Bankmg St<strong>at</strong>istics) <strong>for</strong> the Year 1981 to 2000.<br />

Wh<strong>at</strong> were the trends in the proportion of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

from SCBs? Out of the total agricultural credit, the RRBs provided<br />

two-thirds to one-half whereas the proportion in the case of SBI <strong>and</strong><br />

its associ<strong>at</strong>e banks, n<strong>at</strong>ionalised banks <strong>and</strong> other Scheduled<br />

Commercial Banks was much less. Table 3.2 shows th<strong>at</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

accounted <strong>for</strong> about 16.44 per cent of the total credit in the early<br />

1980s <strong>and</strong> suggests th<strong>at</strong> the banks were meeting the targets fixed on<br />

agricultural lending. However, the proportion progressively declined to<br />

9.92 per cent by 2000. Such a decline was uni<strong>for</strong>m across different<br />

bank groups. Thus, one can conclude th<strong>at</strong> the credit flow to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> even in proportion<strong>at</strong>e terms declined during the re<strong>for</strong>m<br />

period.<br />

10 The growth r<strong>at</strong>e has been calcul<strong>at</strong>ed by using the semi-log model, such as<br />

In Y, ~ \>1 + \>, t + U,<br />

where, t is the time period, PI <strong>and</strong> P, are parameters, <strong>and</strong> U, is the disturbance<br />

term.<br />

After estim<strong>at</strong>ing the above regression model, annual average growth r<strong>at</strong>e (over a<br />

period of time) has been calcul<strong>at</strong>ed by the following way, viz., Annual Average<br />

Growth R<strong>at</strong>e ~ (Antilog of the estim<strong>at</strong>ed P, - 1)* 100.<br />

The same procedure has been applied to calcul<strong>at</strong>e the growth r<strong>at</strong>es wherever they<br />

are required in this study.<br />

54


Table 3.2: Bank Group-wise Share of Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit of<br />

SCBs to Agriculture from Net Bank Credit<br />

(in per cent)<br />

I Total I<br />

Triennium SBI <strong>and</strong> Its N<strong>at</strong>ionalised Foreign Regional Other<br />

Ending I Associ<strong>at</strong>es Banks Banks Rural Scheduled<br />

with<br />

Banks Commercial I<br />

Banks<br />

1983 19.23 15.35 0.00 64.66 5.90 16.44<br />

1986 21.56 14.89 0.00 59.24 5.00 17.05<br />

1989 19.19 16.53 0.00 55.12 4.98 17.46<br />

1990· 16.90 15.44 0.34 54.37 9.60 15.94<br />

1993 15.86 14.18 0.54 50.45 8.14 14.38<br />

1996 12.75 11.97 0.33 49.53 5.63 11.94<br />

1999 11.56 11. 20 0.37 48.35 5.03 10.81<br />

2000· 10.36 10.48 0.36 48.12 4.42<br />

Source: Reserve Bank of India (Bankmg St<strong>at</strong>,st,cs) <strong>for</strong> the Years 1981 to 2000.<br />

Note: • One-year figure<br />

Figures up to 1981- 89 are <strong>for</strong> the period January to December <strong>and</strong><br />

thereafter, <strong>for</strong> the period April to March.<br />

9.92<br />

i<br />

The figures presented in Tables 3_1 <strong>and</strong> 3.2 do not include<br />

credit from co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives, which have traditionally been playing a key<br />

role in so far as short-term credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> is concerned. Table<br />

3.3 includes the co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive credit in the total outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit.<br />

The total outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit disbursed by co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives <strong>and</strong> the SCBs<br />

increased fram an average of Rs_ 8,618 crores in 1981-84 to Rs.62,<br />

608 crares by the year 2000. The co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives accounted <strong>for</strong> more<br />

than one-half of the agricultural credit in early 1980s. Their share had<br />

gradually declined to about one-third by l<strong>at</strong>e 1990s, while th<strong>at</strong> of<br />

SCBs <strong>and</strong> RRBs had increased. An important finding is th<strong>at</strong> although<br />

the share of commercial banks <strong>and</strong> RRBs in the total agricultural<br />

credit disbursed in the country increased during the re<strong>for</strong>m period<br />

(Tables 3.3), the share of these institutions in the net bank credit<br />

declined during this period (Table 3.2).<br />

55


Table 303: Distribution (%) of Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit <strong>for</strong><br />

Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Allied Activities (Short <strong>and</strong> Long-Term) by<br />

Dl off< eren t T L'YI'es 0 fLe n dO 109 I ns tOt 1 u to Ions<br />

=---<br />

Triennium Scheduled Regional Total<br />

Ending with Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives Commercial Banks Rural Banks IRs. in Crores)<br />

(Excludinl( Rims)<br />

1983 55.28 41.49 3.23 8,618<br />

1986 45.9'1 49.01 5.01 13,811<br />

1989 40.18 53.56 6.26 20,922<br />

1990* 38.16 55.20 6.64 27,687<br />

1993 38.51 55.22 6.27 31,573<br />

1996 41.42 51.28 7.30 41,249<br />

1999 39.39 51.95 8.66 54,282<br />

2000* 37.02 53.41 9.57 62,608<br />

Note: * One-year figure. FIgures up to 1981-89 are <strong>for</strong> the penod January to<br />

December <strong>and</strong> thereafter, <strong>for</strong> the period April to March.<br />

Sources: 1) Reserve Bank of India (Report on Currency <strong>and</strong> Finance, Vol. II) from<br />

1981 to 1998.<br />

2) Figures <strong>for</strong> the years 1999 <strong>and</strong> 2000 have been collected from RBI,<br />

2001 (H<strong>and</strong> Book of St<strong>at</strong>istics on Indian Economy).<br />

The growth r<strong>at</strong>e of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> from all the institutions<br />

(in absolute terms) was 11.74 per cent during the period 1981- 2000.<br />

On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the growth r<strong>at</strong>e in real terms 21 was only 3 per cent<br />

<strong>for</strong> the same period (Table 3.4). The growth r<strong>at</strong>es have been uneven<br />

across the sub-periods as well as across the bank groups. The credit<br />

in both absolute <strong>and</strong> real terms grew <strong>at</strong> a much faster r<strong>at</strong>e during the<br />

period 1981-91 as compared to the re<strong>for</strong>m period of 1991-2000. A<br />

similar p<strong>at</strong>tern can be observed across the bank groups also, although<br />

the growth r<strong>at</strong>es of credit flow from RRBs have been higher in both<br />

absolute <strong>and</strong> real terms probably due to a low base as compared to<br />

other financial institutions. The situ<strong>at</strong>ion of co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives appears to<br />

be even grimmer.<br />

" In order to calcul<strong>at</strong>e the growth r<strong>at</strong>es in real term, the outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit amount<br />

in each year has been defl<strong>at</strong>ed by the Consumer Price Index of Agricultural<br />

Labourers taking the year 1986·87 as a base.<br />

56


Table 3.4: Annual Average Growth R<strong>at</strong>es (%) of Outst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

Credit to Agriculture<br />

Scheduled<br />

Year I Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives Commercial Banks Regional Total I<br />

I<br />

(Excludin; RRB~ Rural Banks I<br />

Absolute Real Absolute Real Absolute Real Absolute Real_<br />

1981-1991 9. 83 2. 74 19.66 11. 93 26. I I 17.96 15. 26 7. 82<br />

1992-2000<br />

, 8. 47 0.61 9. 06 I. 16 15. 41 7. 06 9.31 I. 40'<br />

1981-2000 9. 79 I. 91 12. 95 4. II 17.99 8. 75 II. 74 3. 00<br />

Source: I) Reserve Bank of IndIa (Report on Currency <strong>and</strong> FInance, Vol. II) from<br />

1981 to 1998.<br />

2) Figures <strong>for</strong> the years 1999 <strong>and</strong> 2000 have been collected from RBI, 200 I<br />

(H<strong>and</strong> Book of St<strong>at</strong>istics on Indian Economy)<br />

The inter-sub-period differences in the flow of agricultural credit<br />

were also observed from the mean amount of outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit<br />

disbursed by the SCBs including RRBs by <strong>for</strong>mul<strong>at</strong>ing the null<br />

hypothesis th<strong>at</strong> "there is no significant difference in the mean amount<br />

of credit flow of the two samples". The t-test was carried out to test the<br />

different between the means of two samples. The calcul<strong>at</strong>ed t value<br />

(6.26) is gre<strong>at</strong>er than table value (2.10) <strong>at</strong> 5 per cent level. Based on<br />

this result, it is inferred th<strong>at</strong> there is a significant difference in the<br />

mean amount of outst<strong>and</strong>ing agricultural credit between the two subperiods.<br />

Distribution P<strong>at</strong>tern of Agricultural Credit of SCBs<br />

The proportion of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> in the net bank credit declined<br />

from about 17 per cent during the pre-re<strong>for</strong>m period to 10.39 per cent<br />

during the re<strong>for</strong>m period, while the proportion of credit to nonagricultural<br />

sectors continuously increased between these two periods<br />

(Table 3.5). The proportion of agricultural credit <strong>for</strong> the loans in the<br />

size of less than Rs. 25,000 increased during the pre-re<strong>for</strong>m period.<br />

This has been <strong>at</strong>tributed to the prescribed targets on agricultural<br />

lending (Besley 1994), lack of altern<strong>at</strong>ive investment avenues <strong>for</strong> rural<br />

57


ank branches (Rajasekhar <strong>and</strong> Vyasulu 1993) <strong>and</strong> different policies<br />

without reference to the cost of funds (Gad gil 1994; Yaron 1994).<br />

However, the proportion of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>for</strong> both sizes of credit<br />

limit has been declining during the re<strong>for</strong>m period. In the case of non<strong>agriculture</strong><br />

sector, the share of credit flow <strong>for</strong> the credit limit of less<br />

than Rs.2S,000 increased up to the last part of 1980s <strong>and</strong> declined in<br />

the 1990s. Importantly, the share of non-agricultural sector from the<br />

total credit <strong>for</strong> the credit limit of above Rs. 25,000 has been increasing<br />

during the last two decades. Thus, based on the discussion rel<strong>at</strong>ing to<br />

the volume of outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit (Table 3.5), it can be concluded th<strong>at</strong><br />

the banks have been showing bias in favour of non-<strong>agriculture</strong> sector<br />

lending.<br />

Table 3.5: Distribution of Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit to the Total Net<br />

Bank Credit by SCBs (%) by Sectors <strong>and</strong> Credit Limits<br />

Triennium Agricultural Sector Non·Agricultural Sector<br />

Ending Rs.25,OOO Above Sector Rs.25,OOO Above Sector<br />

with <strong>and</strong> Less Rs.25,OOO Total <strong>and</strong> Less Rs.25,OOO Total<br />

1983 8. 67 7. 78 16. 44 10.23 73. 32 83. 56<br />

1986 9. 58 7.47 17.05 12. 10 70. 85 82. 95<br />

1989 10. 39 7. 07 17.46 14. 77 67. 77 82. 54<br />

1991 * 8. 76 6.65 15. 40 13. 77 70. 83 84. 60<br />

1994 7. 36 6. 36 13.72 12. 47 73.81 86. 28<br />

1997 5. 61 5. 77 11. 39 8. 75 79. 86 88.61<br />

2000 4. 09 6. 29 10.39 5. 78 83.83 89.61<br />

Note: * Two-year figure<br />

Source: Reserve Bank of India (Banking St<strong>at</strong>istics) <strong>for</strong> the Years 1981 to 2000.<br />

The percentage of number of loan accounts in the agricultural<br />

sector to the total bank accounts had been declining during both prere<strong>for</strong>m<br />

<strong>and</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m periods (Table 3.6). Interestingly, although the<br />

number of accounts <strong>for</strong> the credit limit of less than Rs. 25,000<br />

declined In the case of the <strong>agriculture</strong> sector during the pre-re<strong>for</strong>m<br />

period, the proportion of amount of credit increased. This indic<strong>at</strong>es<br />

the credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning by banks to minimise transaction costs associ<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

58


with agricultural lending, by reducing the numbers of accounts <strong>for</strong><br />

better supervision <strong>and</strong> monitoring. In the case of non-agricultural<br />

sector, however, the proportions of both accounts <strong>and</strong> amounts <strong>for</strong> the<br />

credit limit of less than Rs. 25,000 increased during the pre-re<strong>for</strong>m<br />

period probably due to higher interest r<strong>at</strong>es on loans to nonagricultural<br />

activities.<br />

Table 3.6: Distribution of Loan Accounts by SCBs (%) by<br />

Sectors <strong>and</strong> Credit Limits<br />

Triennium AJ:ricultural Sector Non-Al!ricultural Sector<br />

Ending Rs.25,OOO Above Rs. Sector Rs.25,000 Above Rs. Sector<br />

with <strong>and</strong> Less 25,000 Total <strong>and</strong> Less 25,000 Total<br />

1983* 49. 30 1. 13 50. 43 46. 28 3. 29 49. 57<br />

1986 48.61 1. 07 49. 68 47. 20 3. 12 50. 32<br />

1989 45. II 1. 13 46. 24 50.47 3. 29 53. 76<br />

1991 ** 43. 46 1. 25 44. 71 51. 50 3. 79 55. 29<br />

1994 41. 02 1. 35 42. 37 53. 25 4. 38 57.63<br />

1997 40. 08 1. 90 41. 98 51. 42 6. 60 58. 02<br />

2000 34. 69 4. 02 38.71 45. 71 15.58 I 61. 29<br />

Note: • One-year fIgure, ** Two-year figure<br />

Figures up to 1981-89 are <strong>for</strong> the period January to December <strong>and</strong> thereafter, <strong>for</strong><br />

the period April to March.<br />

Source: Reserve Bank of India (Banking St<strong>at</strong>istics) <strong>for</strong> the Year 1981 to 2000.<br />

In the case of agricultural loans with credit limit of less than<br />

Rs.25,000, the proportions of accounts to total loan accounts <strong>and</strong><br />

amounts to the total net bank credit declined during the re<strong>for</strong>m<br />

period. Although the proportion of accounts <strong>for</strong> the credit limit of more<br />

than Rs. 25,000 increased in the case of agricultural sector, the net<br />

credit flow declined during the re<strong>for</strong>m period. It can be, there<strong>for</strong>e,<br />

argued th<strong>at</strong> the banks have been adopting both price <strong>and</strong> non-price<br />

credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning mechanisms to minimise lending risks by disbursing<br />

less loan amounts to borrowers in the agricultural sector.<br />

The tendency on the part of banks to provide more funds to the<br />

agricultural activities earning higher interest income seems to have<br />

become more prominent after the deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of lending r<strong>at</strong>e to<br />

59


ultim<strong>at</strong>e borrowers. Since the interest r<strong>at</strong>e charged was unable to<br />

cover the cost of lending (i.e., financial, transaction <strong>and</strong> risk costs).<br />

the lending r<strong>at</strong>e of RRBs was deregul<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>for</strong> all slabs of credit limit<br />

from August 1996. Prior to this, the lending r<strong>at</strong>es of CBs were also<br />

deregul<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>for</strong> the credit limit of over Rs. 2 lakhs from August 1994.<br />

For the credit limit of up to Rs. 2 lakhs, all CBs were asked to charge<br />

a maximum r<strong>at</strong>e of 13.5 per cent per annum. In the case of RRBs, as<br />

the lending r<strong>at</strong>es were totally deregul<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>for</strong> all slabs of credit limit, it<br />

was up to them to charge the r<strong>at</strong>e suitably to meet the cost of lending.<br />

The CBs can also follow the same str<strong>at</strong>egy <strong>for</strong> a credit limit of above<br />

Rs 2 lakhs. In this context, the following inferences can be drawn:<br />

(1) RRBs may find it com<strong>for</strong>table to extend their funds <strong>for</strong><br />

agricultural sector.<br />

(2) CBs may give priority <strong>for</strong> agricultural loan <strong>for</strong> the credit limit of<br />

above Rs. 2 lakhs to earn higher interest margin.<br />

(3) After the interest r<strong>at</strong>e deregul<strong>at</strong>ion, loans from CBs have become<br />

cheaper as compared to those given by RRBs. Under these<br />

circumstances, borrowers may prefer to obtain loan amounts up<br />

to Rs.2 lakhs from CBs provided th<strong>at</strong> service area regul<strong>at</strong>ions are<br />

favourable. The Gupta Committee, however, recommended th<strong>at</strong> a<br />

bank could lend to borrowers outside their service if they chose to<br />

do so.<br />

(4) If the third inference is true, then CBs must be providing more<br />

agricultural credit to the farmers <strong>for</strong> credit up to Rs 2 lakhs by<br />

cross-subsidis<strong>at</strong>ion approach.<br />

As the d<strong>at</strong>a on agricultural lending up to the credit limit of Rs. 2<br />

lakhs are not available separ<strong>at</strong>ely <strong>for</strong> RRBs <strong>and</strong> CBs, it is difficult to<br />

examine the third proposition. In other words, conclusions on the<br />

volume of credit disbursed to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector by RRB <strong>for</strong> this credit<br />

limit are difficult to be drawn. However, in spite of the deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of<br />

lending r<strong>at</strong>es of RRBs, the proportion of amount disbursed to<br />

60


agricultural loans of less than Rs. 2 lakhs by SCBs including RRB<br />

declined from 81.4 per cent in 1992 to 69.79 per cent in 2000 (Table<br />

3.7). In contrast, with complete deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of lending r<strong>at</strong>es in the<br />

case of credit limit of above Rs. 2 lakhs <strong>for</strong> both CB <strong>and</strong> RRBs, the<br />

proportion of outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit increased from 18.6 to 32.21 per cent<br />

during the same period. This indic<strong>at</strong>es the priority to agricultural<br />

loans of above Rs. 2 lakhs in the lending portfolio of CBs. There was<br />

an increase in the proportion of amount disbursed to agricultural<br />

loans in the range of Rs. 25,000 to Rs. 2 lakhs. This implies th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

declining share of agricultural loans up to Rs 2 lakhs was mainly due<br />

to a reduction in the share <strong>for</strong> the credit limit of less than Rs 25,000.<br />

This lends further credence to the earlier finding th<strong>at</strong> there was<br />

widespread credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning practice by CBs <strong>for</strong> borro\vers availing less<br />

than Rs. 25,000 of agricultural loans.<br />

Table 3.7: Distribution of Agricultural Credit by SCBs (%) by<br />

the Type of Lending R<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong> Credit Limits<br />

Triennium Distribution (% I of Agricultural Proportion of Total Credit<br />

Ending Credit with Partially Regul<strong>at</strong>ed Credit with (Amount in !<br />

with Lending R<strong>at</strong>e Deregul<strong>at</strong>ed Rs. Lakhsl I<br />

Lendinl( R<strong>at</strong>e<br />

Rs.25,OOO Above Rs.25,OOO Above Rs. 2<br />

<strong>and</strong> less & up to Rs.2 lakhs Total lakhs<br />

1992 56. 25 25. 15 81. 40 18. 60 1,847,903<br />

1995 52. 62 26. 02 78. 64 21.36 2,329,370<br />

1998 47. 45 26. 07 73. 52 26.48 3.190,188<br />

2000- 36. 64 31. 15 67. 79 32.21 4,326,377<br />

Note: • Two-year figure<br />

Source: Reserve Bank of India (Banking St<strong>at</strong>istics) <strong>for</strong> the Year 1981 to 2000<br />

The number of loan accounts <strong>for</strong> all the sectors <strong>and</strong> also<br />

individual sectors, though rapidly increased during the pre-re<strong>for</strong>m<br />

period, registered neg<strong>at</strong>ive growth r<strong>at</strong>es during the re<strong>for</strong>m period.<br />

Interestingly, the neg<strong>at</strong>ive growth r<strong>at</strong>es in the loan accounts <strong>for</strong> both<br />

agricultural <strong>and</strong> non-agricultural sectors was solely due to the<br />

reduction in the number of accounts <strong>for</strong> the credit limit of Rs. 25,000<br />

61


<strong>and</strong> less. This suggests the neglect of small borrowers by seBs. This<br />

also implies th<strong>at</strong> the access of <strong>for</strong>mal credit to small borrowers was<br />

adversely affected. The relevant question, there<strong>for</strong>e, is wh<strong>at</strong> factors<br />

determine the access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit.<br />

Table 3.8: Credit Limit-wise Annual Average Growth R<strong>at</strong>es of<br />

Loan Accounts<br />

(in per cent<br />

Agricultural Sector Non·~iculture Sector For All<br />

Period Rs. Above Sector Rs. Above Sector Sectors<br />

25,000 Rs. Total 25,000 Rs. Total<br />

<strong>and</strong> Less 25,000 <strong>and</strong> Less 25,000<br />

1983-91 7. 94 I!. 94 8.03 I!. 83 12. 50 11. 87 10. 03<br />

1991-00 - 5. 33 16. 29 - 4.03 - 5. 18 19.70 - 1. 52 - 2.54<br />

1983-00 1. 05 11. 54 1. 57 3. 28 13. 66 4.63 3. 26<br />

Sources: Reserve Bank of India (Bankmg St<strong>at</strong>istics) <strong>for</strong> the Year 1981 to 2000<br />

Achievement of SCBs in Agricultural Finance<br />

The outreach ef<strong>for</strong>ts of the FRBS into the rural areas, in general <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>, in particular, yielded positive results in quantit<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

terms. The outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> by SeBs (including<br />

RRBs) increased from Rs. 4,863 crores in 1981 to Rs. 45,638 crores<br />

by 2000 (Reserve Bank of India 1981 <strong>and</strong> 2000). However, the share<br />

of agricultural credit to the net bank credit declined in the last two<br />

decades. Table 3.9, which presents the d<strong>at</strong>a on agricultural lending<br />

during the period 1981-2000, shows th<strong>at</strong> the SeBs hardly achieved<br />

the prescribed targets given to agricultural lending. Be<strong>for</strong>e October<br />

1993, only direct <strong>finance</strong> to <strong>agriculture</strong> was targeted <strong>and</strong> banks were<br />

supposed to lend 18 per cent of the net bank credit by 1990. But the<br />

achievement r<strong>at</strong>e of direct <strong>finance</strong> to <strong>agriculture</strong> was 13. 84 per cent<br />

(Table 3.9), well below the target of 18 per cent.<br />

62


Table 3.9: Proportion of Credit Advanced to Agriculture from<br />

Net Bank Credit of SCBs (Includif!g,--,R::=R,~B"s:L'-c=-:--:--_______ ---,<br />

Type of Triennium EndinJ: With !<br />

Advance ~3 1986 1989 1990' 1993 1996 1999 2000';<br />

Direct 12.91 14.28 15.21 13.84 12.59 10.23 9.20 8. 38 ~<br />

Finance Il+ O. 28JJ:- 1.79Ll- 4.16) I (- 5. 41) I (- 3. 2TI.J- 4. 30Jjl- 5. 1~<br />

'I<br />

Indirect 3. 53 2. 77 2. 25 2. 10 I. 79 I. 71 I. 62 I. 54<br />

Finance<br />

Total 16.44 17.05 17.46 15.94 14.38 II. 94 10.81 9.92<br />

I (- 2. 79) I (- 2. 88) (- 2.96) I<br />

Advance I (- 6. 06) 1(- 7. 19) 1[- 8. 081.<br />

Net Bank<br />

Credit (in 33,737 52.840 78,696 104,312 141,125213,841 332,248460,081<br />

Rs. Crores)<br />

Note: • One-year figure.<br />

1) Figures in parentheses represent shortfall or excess of target fixed <strong>for</strong><br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> from net bank credit <strong>at</strong> different points in time.<br />

2) Figures up to 1981-89 are <strong>for</strong> the period January to Decem ber <strong>and</strong><br />

thereafter <strong>for</strong> the period April to March.<br />

Source: Reserve Bank of India (Banking St<strong>at</strong>istics) <strong>for</strong> the Years 1981 to 2000.<br />

Since banks could not achieve the given target of direct <strong>finance</strong>,<br />

indirect <strong>finance</strong> to <strong>agriculture</strong> was brought under the purview of<br />

<strong>finance</strong> to <strong>agriculture</strong>, <strong>and</strong> clubbed with direct advances <strong>for</strong> meeting<br />

the 18 per cent sub-target to <strong>agriculture</strong> from October 1993. However,<br />

in order to ensure th<strong>at</strong> the focus of banks on direct agricultural<br />

lending was not diluted, the "indirect" advance to <strong>agriculture</strong> was<br />

stipul<strong>at</strong>ed to be one-fourth of total agricultural lending or 4.5 per cent<br />

of net bank credit. In order to ensure the inputs to allied agricultural<br />

activities of dairy, poultry, piggery <strong>and</strong> fishery, advances up.to Rs. 5<br />

lakhs <strong>for</strong> financing the distribution of inputs <strong>for</strong> the allied activities<br />

were reckoned as indirect agricultural advances under the priority<br />

sector effective from May 1994 [RBI 1993-941. Besides, the <strong>finance</strong><br />

extended to dealers in drip irrig<strong>at</strong>ion, sprinkler irrig<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong><br />

agricultural machinery was classified as "indirect <strong>finance</strong> to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>" <strong>and</strong> clubbed with the priority sector advances. Despite<br />

these ef<strong>for</strong>ts, the proportion of indirect advance to <strong>agriculture</strong> to net<br />

bank credit varied between 1.50 <strong>and</strong> 2 per cent <strong>for</strong> the last 8 years.<br />

Importantly, the total agricultural advances rapidly declined to 9.92<br />

6' .'


per cent of net bank credit by 2000 (Table 3.9), <strong>and</strong> the gap between<br />

target <strong>and</strong> achievement r<strong>at</strong>es <strong>for</strong> both direct <strong>and</strong> indirect advances<br />

was widening in the 1990s.<br />

The distribution of direct <strong>finance</strong> by size-classes of farmers<br />

(Table 3.10) during the last two decades shows th<strong>at</strong> the proportion of<br />

the amount disbursed <strong>for</strong> marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers increased up to<br />

1980s. In 1990s, however, the share of the marginal farmers had<br />

declined from 29.7 to 23.8 per cent. At the same time, there was a<br />

marginal increase in the proportion of credit disbursed to small<br />

farmers <strong>and</strong> substantial increase in the same to medium/large<br />

farmers in this decade. This further supports the earlier argument<br />

th<strong>at</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal financial ~gencies preferred lending to better-off farmer3.<br />

Table 3.10: Distribution (%) of Direct Finance to Farmers by<br />

SCBs (Short <strong>and</strong> Long-Term Loans) by Size-Classes of<br />

La n db 0 ld· 109<br />

Triennium Marginal Small (2.5 Medium <strong>and</strong> Total<br />

Ending With 15 acres) IRs. Crores)<br />

1983 27. 3 19.4 53. 3 825. 0<br />

1986 26. 8 25. 3 47. 9 1,900.1<br />

1989 27. 8 25. 9 46. 3 2,958.5<br />

1991' 29. 7 24. 7 45. 5 3, 722. 3<br />

1994 28. 5 25. 1 46. 4 4, 278. 4<br />

1997 25.8 25. 1 49. 1 7, 589. 6<br />

2000 23. 8 25. 6 50. 6 11, 790. 1<br />

Note: * Two year figure.<br />

Figures gives <strong>for</strong> all the years are <strong>for</strong> the period july-june except <strong>for</strong> the<br />

year 1981 <strong>and</strong> 1982 (April-March).<br />

Source: Reserve Bank of India, 2001 (H<strong>and</strong>book of St<strong>at</strong>istics on Indian Economy)<br />

The changes in the distribution of loan accounts by size-classes<br />

of farmers during the period 1981 to 2000 (Table 3_11) reveal th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

proportion of accounts held by marginal farmers was generally large in<br />

the early 1980s as compared to the l<strong>at</strong>e 1990s. On the other h<strong>and</strong>,<br />

the proportion of loan accounts held by small <strong>and</strong> medium/large<br />

farmers increased, albeit with fluctu<strong>at</strong>ions. This suggests th<strong>at</strong> a<br />

64


larger number of medium <strong>and</strong> large sIze farmers (above 5 acres of<br />

l<strong>and</strong>) were obtaining credit from banks as compared with marginal<br />

farmers.<br />

Table 3.11: Distribution or Disbursement Loan Accounts on<br />

Direct Finance to Farmers by seBs (Short-Term <strong>and</strong> Long-<br />

Term Loans)<br />

Triennium Up to 2. Above 2. 5 Above 5 Total No. of<br />

Ending 5 Acres Acres to 5 Acres Accounts<br />

With (in %1 Acres (in 0/1 (in %1 (in OOOsl<br />

1983 51. 1 24. 0 24. 9 2,329.9<br />

1986 47. 2 29. 8 22.9 3, 960. 2<br />

1989 46. 8 31. 0 22. 2 4, 608. 4<br />

1991' 47. 7 30. 4 21. 9 4, 209. 3<br />

1994 44. 2 31. 2 24. 7 4,241.7<br />

1997 39. 0 31. 1 29. 9 5,241.2<br />

2000 39. 8 32. 8 27. 5 5,657.9<br />

Note: • Two year fIgure.<br />

Figures given <strong>for</strong> all the years are <strong>for</strong> the period July·June except <strong>for</strong> the<br />

year 1981 <strong>and</strong> 1982 (April-MarchI.<br />

Source: Reserve Bank of India, 2001 (H<strong>and</strong>book of St<strong>at</strong>istics on Indian EconomYI.<br />

Credit Subsidy in Indian Agriculture<br />

Subsidised credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> through concessional interest r<strong>at</strong>es<br />

<strong>and</strong> high defaults have been posing a thre<strong>at</strong> to the financial viability of<br />

credit institutions. If the interest income is gre<strong>at</strong>er than or <strong>at</strong> least<br />

equal to the cost of lending (break-even condition), this may positively<br />

influence the financial institutions to step up the supply of<br />

agricultural credit. However, default r<strong>at</strong>e plays an important role in<br />

determining the break-even level of interest r<strong>at</strong>e. Higher the default<br />

r<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong> higher the break-even interest r<strong>at</strong>e th<strong>at</strong> has to be charged.<br />

Since it was difficult to cover the costs of lending, the RBI initi<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

several measures towards deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of interest r<strong>at</strong>es in 1990s. In<br />

the case of RRBs <strong>and</strong> co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives the lending r<strong>at</strong>es were totally<br />

deregul<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>for</strong> all slabs of credit limit. For Commercial Banks, only<br />

the interest r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> the credit limit of above Rs. 2 lakhs was<br />

deregul<strong>at</strong>ed.<br />

65


In the deregul<strong>at</strong>ed interest r<strong>at</strong>e structure, the lending r<strong>at</strong>e<br />

varies with the loan size. However, <strong>for</strong> the credit limit of less than Rs 2<br />

lakhs in CBs, the hitherto prevalent distinction between preferred <strong>and</strong><br />

other investment was abolished. <strong>and</strong> the maximum interest r<strong>at</strong>e fixed<br />

was 13.5 per cent per annum.<br />

Now, the question is whether this<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>e was sufficient to cover the costs. If no, the CBs might<br />

have to cross-subsidise to the farmers taking loan amounts less than<br />

Rs. 2 iakhs with interest income earned from lending to the credit<br />

limit of more than Rs. 2 lakhs by pumping more funds into the l<strong>at</strong>ter<br />

c<strong>at</strong>egory belonging to either <strong>agriculture</strong> or non-<strong>agriculture</strong>. This<br />

discussion raises the following questions:<br />

1. Are the interest r<strong>at</strong>es sufficient to cover the costs of lending?<br />

2. If no, is there cross-subsidis<strong>at</strong>ion? If yes, is it confined to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> or non-<strong>agriculture</strong>?<br />

3. Does credit subsidy reduce the supply of agricultural credit?<br />

The answer to the first question needs a discussion <strong>and</strong><br />

analysis on credit subsidy. Credit subsidy can be calcul<strong>at</strong>ed in two<br />

different ways. The first method consists of two components, namely,<br />

interest subsidy <strong>and</strong> default subsidy. Interest subsidy accrues to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> due to concessional r<strong>at</strong>e of interest being charged to this<br />

sector vis-a-vis the other sectors of the economy. Default subsidy22<br />

accrues to agricultural lending in the <strong>for</strong>m of bad debts. Credit<br />

subsidy to <strong>agriculture</strong> can be obtained by adding these two subsidies.<br />

The second method perceives credit subsidy as the difference between<br />

cost of supplying credit to agricultural sector (including defaults) <strong>and</strong><br />

r<strong>at</strong>e of interest received from agricultural sector only.<br />

" It is worth mentioning here th<strong>at</strong> default also oCCurs in non-agricultural sector<br />

lending <strong>and</strong> th<strong>at</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e. one has to take into account onl\' the additional<br />

default In credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> while calcul<strong>at</strong>ing default subsid\· .•<br />

66


Due to the practice of uni<strong>for</strong>m interest r<strong>at</strong>es on loan amounts<br />

less than Rs. 2 lakhs in the case of CBs, the interest subsidy may not<br />

exist in the case of this credit limit regardless of the purpose. So,<br />

according to the first method, the credit subsidy arises mainly due to<br />

the default subsidy. Importantly, due to difficulty in the availability of<br />

d<strong>at</strong>a on bad <strong>and</strong> doubtful debts, it may be difficult to estim<strong>at</strong>e the<br />

credit subsidy by applying the first method. In the present study,<br />

credit subsidy has been calcul<strong>at</strong>ed by applying the second method on<br />

the basis of certain assumptions mentioned <strong>at</strong> different places in the<br />

ensuing paragraphs.<br />

The Agricultural Credit Review Committee (ACRC) had<br />

envisaged three broad c.Htegories of C'osts in the agricultural credit<br />

system. These were financial costs 23 , transaction costs 2 4, <strong>and</strong> risk<br />

costs or costs of bad debts 25 . Table 3.12 provides the costs estim<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

by the committee <strong>for</strong> different financial institutions <strong>for</strong> the period<br />

1983-84 to 1985-86.<br />

Table 3.12: Estim<strong>at</strong>ed Lending Costs Per Rs.I00 Outst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

Loan<br />

(in Rs.1<br />

In.tltutions Financial Transaction Risk Cost Total Cost<br />

Cost Cost<br />

PACS 9. 90 5.40 1. 00 16. 30<br />

LDB 6. 51 4.04 1. 00 11. 55<br />

RRB 7. 80 6. 90 1. 00 15. 70<br />

CB 7. 48 6. 00 1. 00 14. 48<br />

.<br />

Source: Khusro CommIttee, 1989, Chapter XVIII .<br />

13 A fmancial cost refers to actual costs of raising financial resources. It is computed<br />

as the interest on borrowing <strong>and</strong> deposits.<br />

14 Transaction costs are organis<strong>at</strong>ional costs <strong>for</strong> carrying out the day to dav<br />

institutional oper<strong>at</strong>ions such as staff salaries <strong>and</strong> allowances, bUilding rent,<br />

travel, printing <strong>and</strong> st<strong>at</strong>ionary, postage <strong>and</strong> telegram, audit <strong>and</strong> training, etc.<br />

15 R' IS k cost consIsts . of actual write-offs or reserve cre<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>for</strong> bad <strong>and</strong> doubtful<br />

debts.<br />

67


Gadgil (1994) argues th<strong>at</strong> the transaction costs In 1990s were<br />

higher than the above due to rising staff salaries (80 per cent of the<br />

transaction costs, according to Khusro Committee, was manpower<br />

rel<strong>at</strong>ed) <strong>and</strong> escal<strong>at</strong>ion in the cost of office rent, transport, st<strong>at</strong>ionary,<br />

postage, telephone charges, etc. This study, there<strong>for</strong>e, assumes th<strong>at</strong><br />

the transaction costs in 1990s were higher by one percentage point<br />

than the estim<strong>at</strong>es provided by Khusro Committee, <strong>and</strong> th<strong>at</strong> the risk<br />

cost was constant while calcul<strong>at</strong>ing the lending cost. Since our focus<br />

is on the credit extended by all SCBs (including RRBs), we have<br />

considered the average of financial <strong>and</strong> transaction costs as estim<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

by the Khusro Committee of both c<strong>at</strong>egories of banks in calcul<strong>at</strong>ing<br />

the cost of lending to agricultural sector. Furthermore, it is also<br />

assumed th<strong>at</strong> the cost of lending is the same <strong>for</strong> short <strong>and</strong> long-term<br />

agricultural credit. By taking all these assumptions into account, the<br />

lending costs <strong>for</strong> agricultural credit 26 have been calcul<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>for</strong> the<br />

study period in Table 3.13. Given these costs of lending, the interest<br />

income on lending to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector is estim<strong>at</strong>ed below to see the<br />

extent of credit subsidy.<br />

Table 3.13: Cost of Lending to Agricultural Sector Per Rs.I00<br />

o u tst an d' 1D~ C re d't 1 0 f C Bs Inc 1 u d' lDJ:! RRBs<br />

Year Average Average Average Total<br />

Financial Cost Transaction Cost Risk Cost Cost<br />

1981 to 1990 7. 64 6.45 1. 00 15. 09<br />

1991 to 2000 7.64 7. 45 1. 00 16. 09<br />

26 These costs, especially financial, were marginally lower than those calcul<strong>at</strong>ed bv<br />

Gadgil 11997). Using the d<strong>at</strong>a on structure-wise deposits in CBs as on March<br />

1993 <strong>and</strong> applying the January 1997 interest r<strong>at</strong>es on deposits Inil on current<br />

deposits, 4.5 per cent on savings bank deposits <strong>and</strong> 8- I 3 per cent on term<br />

deposits), he calcul<strong>at</strong>ed the weighted average annual cost of deposits <strong>at</strong> 7.90 per<br />

cent. If the cost of deposits as estim<strong>at</strong>ed by Gadgil had been considered as the<br />

finanCIal costs, the lending costs would have been more than wh<strong>at</strong> the study has<br />

calcubted.<br />

68


The d<strong>at</strong>a on the amount of agricultural loan outst<strong>and</strong>ing by<br />

SCBs (including RRB) <strong>at</strong> different interest r<strong>at</strong>es were used to estim<strong>at</strong>e<br />

the interest income on agricultural lending. These d<strong>at</strong>a rel<strong>at</strong>e to<br />

accounts with credit limit of over Rs 25,000 <strong>for</strong> the period 1981 to<br />

1998, <strong>and</strong> the credit limit of above Rs 2 lakhs <strong>for</strong> the years 1999 <strong>and</strong><br />

2000. Since the lending r<strong>at</strong>e was, by <strong>and</strong> large, fixed <strong>for</strong> the credit<br />

limit of less than Rs. 2 lakhs, the d<strong>at</strong>a were accordingly adjusted In<br />

calcul<strong>at</strong>ing the interest income on agricultural lending.<br />

The annual average interest income <strong>for</strong> Rs. 100 outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> can be calcul<strong>at</strong>ed as:<br />

II<br />

Y (rml x X ml )<br />

m=1<br />

-- -------(1)<br />

Where,<br />

rmt = the mean of mth interest range <strong>for</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> sector <strong>for</strong> the tth<br />

period<br />

Xmt = the outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit in mth interest range <strong>for</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

the tth year<br />

X, = total outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit <strong>for</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>for</strong> the tthyear<br />

Here, we define credit subsidy as the difference between cost of<br />

providing credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> interest r<strong>at</strong>e earned on outst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

agricultural advances adjusted <strong>for</strong> defaults. Thus, the credit subsidy<br />

(S,) <strong>for</strong> Rs 100 can be calcul<strong>at</strong>ed as:<br />

St = Ct- rt - - -- - -- - - -- - - - - - - (2)<br />

(where Ct is the cost of lending to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector).<br />

69


The resulting figure of S, gives the credit subsidy per Rs. 100 of<br />

outst<strong>and</strong>ing loan. Accordingly, total credit subsidy to <strong>agriculture</strong> (Lr)<br />

sector can be obtained as:<br />

Lr = (S, / 100) X, -- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - (3)<br />

Based on the above model, credit subsidy on agricultural <strong>finance</strong> has<br />

been estim<strong>at</strong>ed in Table 3. 14.<br />

Table 3.14: Cost, Interest Income <strong>and</strong> Credit Subsidy to<br />

A ~grlCU . It ura IS ec t or<br />

For the Credit Limit (CL) of Total Agricultural Credit<br />

Year C, More Than Rs. 25,000 (including CL <strong>for</strong> < Rs. 25,000)<br />

r, 5, Lt (Rs. Crore) r, 5, Lt (Rs. Crore) .<br />

I 2 3 4 5 6 7 8<br />

1981 15. 09 13. 50 1. 59 41.69 13. 50 1. 59 77. 33<br />

1982 15. 09 13. 24 1. 85 54.62 13.26 1. 83 103. 19<br />

1983 15. 09 12. 45 2. 64 70. 10 13. 05 2. 04 125. 29<br />

1984 15. 09 11.99 3. 10 123. 98 12. 75 2. 31<br />

.00<br />

J.vv. ~v<br />

1985 15. 09 12. 00 3.09 117. 17 12. 86 2. 23 197. 35<br />

1986 15. 09 12. 06 3. 03 122. 67 12. 92 2. 17 219.27<br />

1987 15. 09 12. 16 2.93 146. 78 12. 95 2. 14 259. 20<br />

1988 15. 09 12. 20 2. 89 158. 70 12.97 2. 12 285. 92<br />

1989 15. 09 11. 37 3. 72 229. 94 12. 64 2. 45 374. 01<br />

1990 15. 09 12. 83 2. 26 154. 54 13. 22 1. 87 310.91<br />

1991 16. 09 13. 51 2. 58 214.63 13. 50 2. 59 481. 05<br />

1992 16. 09 14. 95 1. 14 103. 15 14. 15 1. 94 392.61<br />

1993 16. 09 15.71 O. 38 39. 66 14. 55 1. 54 339. 73<br />

1994 16. 09 15. 57 O. 52 55. 66 14. 47 1. 62 370. 54<br />

1995 16. 09 15. 43 O. 66 78.95 14. 43 1. 66 414. 14<br />

1996 16. 09 15. 85 O. 24 34.93 14. 69 1. 40 403. 33<br />

1997 16. 09 15. 86 O. 23 38. 54 14. 75 1. 34 423. 90<br />

1998 16. 09 15. 37 O. 72 136. 63 14. 51 1. 58 557. 15<br />

1999 16. 09 14. 45 1. 64 414. 00 14. 09 2. 00 817.79<br />

2000 16. 09 14. 22 1. 87 553. 08 13. 97 2. 12 967. 53<br />

..<br />

Note: As the cel1mg mterest r<strong>at</strong>e IS stIpul<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>at</strong> 13.5 per cent per annum <strong>for</strong> the<br />

credit limit of up to Rs. 2 1akhs <strong>for</strong> CBs, the same has been assumed as the<br />

maximum interest r<strong>at</strong>e while calcul<strong>at</strong>ing agricultural credit subsidy.<br />

""<br />

Column 7 in Table 3.14 shows th<strong>at</strong> the credit subsidy per<br />

Rs.I00 outst<strong>and</strong>ing loan to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector was more during prere<strong>for</strong>m<br />

period as compared to the re<strong>for</strong>m period. It was also true <strong>for</strong><br />

the credit limit of more than Rs.25,000 (see column 4). This reduction<br />

in credit subsidy during the re<strong>for</strong>m period can be <strong>at</strong>tributed to the<br />

70


interest r<strong>at</strong>e deregul<strong>at</strong>ion. The interest Income from agricultural<br />

lending <strong>for</strong> the credit limit of more than Rs.25,000 (column 3) was<br />

gre<strong>at</strong>er than the interest income <strong>for</strong> the credit limit of less than Rs.<br />

25,000 since the year 1991. However, the interest income from the<br />

<strong>for</strong>mer slab of credit limit also did not cover the costs of lending. This<br />

implies th<strong>at</strong> cross subsidis<strong>at</strong>ion within the agricultural sector is not<br />

possible, since the cost of providing service is more than the income.<br />

Thus, the possibility of cross-subsidy within the agricultural<br />

lending in India is ruled out. This is evident in Table 3.14 th<strong>at</strong><br />

lending costs in the agricultural sector as a whole were more than the<br />

income <strong>for</strong> the last two decades. The inference is, there<strong>for</strong>e, th<strong>at</strong><br />

agricultural lending in Innia needs_credit subsidy. The amount of<br />

credit subsidy to <strong>agriculture</strong> by all SCBs (including RRB) increased<br />

from Rs. 77.33 crares in 1981 to Rs. 967. 53 crares in 2000. Such a<br />

rapid increase in the amount of credit subsidy to <strong>agriculture</strong> implies<br />

th<strong>at</strong> banks had been pressurised to cross-subsidise agricultural sector<br />

from the income gener<strong>at</strong>ed by lending to the other sectors. This might<br />

have resulted in two responses from the banks: Alloc<strong>at</strong>ion of more<br />

loanable funds to non-agricultural sector <strong>and</strong>/ or disbursing less<br />

credit to <strong>agriculture</strong>. Has this really happened? The discussion also<br />

calls <strong>for</strong> analysis of the following questions: Is increasing lending r<strong>at</strong>e<br />

a solution to reduce the r<strong>at</strong>e of credit subsidy? To wh<strong>at</strong> extent the<br />

supply of agricultural credit is elastic to interest r<strong>at</strong>e change? These<br />

are analysed in section 3.7.<br />

Number of Rural Bank Branches <strong>and</strong> Agricultural Credit<br />

The other important aspect of agricultural credit system IS the<br />

availability of banking facilities <strong>at</strong> reasonable distance. In the wake of<br />

losses to rural bank branches, it was recommended to close down the<br />

71


loss-making branches or to merge with the other banks 27 As a result<br />

of this policy decision, there has been a marginal decline in the<br />

number of rural branches from 1994. In the Southern, Western <strong>and</strong><br />

Central Regions of the country, the r<strong>at</strong>e of decline was more<br />

pronounced (Table 3.15). A reduction in the number of bank branches<br />

has not taken place in semi-urban, urban <strong>and</strong> metro areas. The<br />

decline in the number of rural bank branches together with increasing<br />

popul<strong>at</strong>ion pressure may have resulted in the following: i) A reduction<br />

in the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong>; ii) loan dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> deposit supply<br />

may have been adversely affected; iii) the growth of priv<strong>at</strong>e investment<br />

<strong>for</strong> agricultural development <strong>and</strong> financial deepening of the rural<br />

sector may have been severely affected; <strong>and</strong>, iv) the access to banking<br />

facility hy rural popul<strong>at</strong>ion may have come dO'Nn.<br />

Table 3.15: Region-wise Growth R<strong>at</strong>e of Rural Bank Branches<br />

(in per cent)<br />

Year Northern North Eastern Central Western Southern Total<br />

Region Eastern Region Region Region Region<br />

Region<br />

1981-91 5. 17 10. 01 7. 79 7. 37 5. 19 3. 84 6. 05<br />

1992-00 - 0.77 - 1. 12 - 0.64 -1. 36 -1. 32 -1. 50 -1. 13<br />

1981-00 1. 97 4. 34 3. 44 2. 63 1. 79 1. 05 2. 28<br />

Sources: Reserve Bank of IndIa (Bankmg St<strong>at</strong>IstIcs) from the year 1981 to 2000.<br />

Determinants of Supply of Agricultural Credit<br />

An analysis of the achievement of SCBs in the provisioning of<br />

agricultural credit reveals th<strong>at</strong> the banks did not even reach the set<br />

targets. Importantly, the proportion of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> in the total<br />

net bank credit declined especially during the re<strong>for</strong>m period. Is<br />

agricultural lending not a profitable avenue <strong>for</strong> banks? Is the interest<br />

income from <strong>agriculture</strong> sector is less <strong>for</strong> the banks? We, there<strong>for</strong>e,<br />

examine the factors preventing banks from extending credit to<br />

21 In the case of RRB, the bank branches were merged with the sponsoring bank.


agricultural sector. However, this analysis has been done only <strong>for</strong><br />

credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> from scheduled commercial banks, <strong>and</strong> not<br />

from co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives <strong>for</strong> two reasons. First, the banking sector re<strong>for</strong>ms<br />

have hardly any impact on the financial p<strong>at</strong>tern of the Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives.<br />

Second, with widespread practices of rescheduling of loans (even in<br />

the event of non-repayment), the d<strong>at</strong>a on <strong>finance</strong>s provided by cooper<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

credit institutions is unreliable. The a priori model on<br />

supply of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> is specified with the following variables.<br />

(a) Investment in Securities<br />

In a regul<strong>at</strong>ed lending system, given the interest r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> default<br />

risk, the bankers may be more interested in investing their funds<br />

in government <strong>and</strong> othp.r approved secl.lriti~s. Th~ increasing<br />

proportion of investment in securities out of total deposits may<br />

leave the banks with less loanable funds. It may adversely affect<br />

the channelis<strong>at</strong>ion of credit to different sectors of the economy, in<br />

general, <strong>and</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong>, in particular. This may also neg<strong>at</strong>ively<br />

affect the Credit-Deposit R<strong>at</strong>io. Thus, INVS is expected to have<br />

neg<strong>at</strong>ive associ<strong>at</strong>ion with credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong>.<br />

(b) Rural Coverage of Banks<br />

DUring the post-n<strong>at</strong>ionalis<strong>at</strong>ion period, banks were directed by the<br />

RBI to give priority to rural <strong>and</strong> non-banked areas in the bankbranch<br />

expansion to enhance the credit availability to the needy.<br />

However, the problems of the FRBS, viz., mounting overdues, poor<br />

quality of lending <strong>and</strong> recalcitrant <strong>at</strong>titude among borrowers<br />

contributed to the cumul<strong>at</strong>ive loses, adversely affected the viability<br />

<strong>and</strong> efficiency of the banking system. During the re<strong>for</strong>m years, the<br />

banks were directed to close down their loss making branches or<br />

73


74<br />

merge them with other banks. Thus, closure of loss-making banks<br />

together with the increasing popul<strong>at</strong>ion pressure may have reduced<br />

the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong>, <strong>and</strong> hence, the variable of RBB is<br />

expected to have neg<strong>at</strong>ive associ<strong>at</strong>ion with credit flow to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>.<br />

(c) Lending R<strong>at</strong>e on Agricultural Credit<br />

From the supply side, interest r<strong>at</strong>e plays an important role in the<br />

flow of credit. If the interest income is gre<strong>at</strong>er or <strong>at</strong> least equal to<br />

the cost of lending, it may positively influence the financial<br />

institutions to increase the supply of agricultural credit. Thus, a<br />

higher lending r<strong>at</strong>e is expected to increase the supply of credit to<br />

equ<strong>at</strong>ion (1).<br />

(d) Credit Subsidy<br />

Credit subsidy is the difference between cost of providing credit to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> interest r<strong>at</strong>e earned on outst<strong>and</strong>ing agricultural<br />

advances adjusted <strong>for</strong> defaults. Increase in the r<strong>at</strong>e of credit<br />

subsidy may reduce the supply of agricultural credit. Equ<strong>at</strong>ion (2)<br />

gives the details on the measurement of this variable.<br />

(e) Agricultural Credit Supplied by the Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives<br />

An increase in the total agricultural credit supplied by the cooper<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

institutions may reduce the extent of credit supply by the<br />

commercial banks <strong>and</strong> RRB. The commercial banks, including the<br />

RRB, are expected to follow a policy of mutual substitutability with<br />

co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive institutions in the provisioning of agricultural credit.


The OLS method has been applied here to examine the impact of the<br />

above on the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> by the SCBs. However, as per<br />

the Durbin W<strong>at</strong>son 'd'Test positive auto correl<strong>at</strong>ion was observed in<br />

the estim<strong>at</strong>ion. The Cocharine-Orentt method was applied to correct<br />

the same. The description expected sign <strong>and</strong> estim<strong>at</strong>ed results of the<br />

variables used in the analysis have been reported in the Table 3.16.<br />

Table 3.16: Description, Expected Sign <strong>and</strong> Coefficient of<br />

Variables Used in the Equ<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

[Deoendent variable = Prooortion of agricultural credit from total bank credit]<br />

Variable Description Expected Coefficient . t - values<br />

Sign<br />

Constant 26.82 ** 2. 86<br />

INVS<br />

Proportion of investment in<br />

government <strong>and</strong> other approved - - o. 16 ***<br />

securities from total bank deposits<br />

RBB Proportion of rural bank from total + 0.52 * I<br />

number of banks branches<br />

INTR Interest r<strong>at</strong>e per Rs. 100 + - 2. 44 *<br />

outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit<br />

CS Credit subsidy per Rs. 100 - -1.57***<br />

outst<strong>and</strong>ing loan<br />

ACSCOP Proportion of agricultural credit - O. 05<br />

extended by the Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives<br />

R-sauared 0.97<br />

Durbin - W<strong>at</strong>son st<strong>at</strong> 2. 30<br />

Number of observ<strong>at</strong>ions 20<br />

Note: * 1 % level of SIgnIficance; ** 5 % level of SIgnIficance; *** 10 % level of<br />

significance<br />

-1. 86<br />

8. 83<br />

- 4. 74<br />

-1. 84<br />

1. 09<br />

As expected, most of the parameters have the expected sign<br />

except INTR <strong>and</strong> ACSCOP. The neg<strong>at</strong>ive <strong>and</strong> st<strong>at</strong>istically significant<br />

coefficient of INVS indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> proportion of investment in<br />

government <strong>and</strong> other approved securities from total bank deposits<br />

was neg<strong>at</strong>ively associ<strong>at</strong>ed with the share of <strong>agriculture</strong> sector from net<br />

bank credit. An increase in the investment in securities by one per<br />

cent reduces the supply of agricultural credit by 0.16 per cent.<br />

Probably, the positive returns have been giving incentives to divert<br />

more funds on investment securities, <strong>and</strong> leaving the bank with less<br />

75


loanable funds. This, in turn, reduces the supply of credit to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> sector. Coefficient of RBB is positive <strong>and</strong> significant <strong>at</strong> 1<br />

per cent level, which implies th<strong>at</strong> improved banking coverage in rural<br />

areas steps up the supply of agricultural credit. The coefficient of INTR<br />

is neg<strong>at</strong>ive <strong>and</strong> significant, which is contradictory to the theoretical<br />

argument th<strong>at</strong> an increase in the lending r<strong>at</strong>e will increase the supply<br />

of agricultural credit. Hence, increasing the lending r<strong>at</strong>e may not be<br />

an important means to increase the supply of agricultural credit. It<br />

has been argued th<strong>at</strong> an increasing interest r<strong>at</strong>e or coll<strong>at</strong>eral<br />

requirement increases the risks of the bank's loan portfolio by either<br />

discouraging safer investor or by inducing borrowers to invest in<br />

riskier project <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e, decreases the bank profit (Stiglitz <strong>and</strong><br />

Weiss 1981). With the deregulFltion of interest r<strong>at</strong>es in 1990s, the<br />

extent to which this would be beneficial to enhance the supply of<br />

agricultural credit is questionable.<br />

The neg<strong>at</strong>ive <strong>and</strong> significant coefficient of credit subsidy (CS)<br />

implies th<strong>at</strong> 1 per cent increase in credit subsidy reduces the supply<br />

of agricultural credit by 1.57 per cent. In this context, can we adopt<br />

increasing lending r<strong>at</strong>e as a means to reduce the r<strong>at</strong>e of credit<br />

subsidy? Since increasing the lending r<strong>at</strong>e itself reduces the supply of<br />

agricultural credit, this cannot be a sound approach to reduce the<br />

credit subsidy. As agricultural lending needs credit subsidy, the net<br />

interest income out of deployment of funds in the <strong>agriculture</strong> sector is<br />

neg<strong>at</strong>ive. Thus, the profit oriented norms probably encourage the<br />

bankers to release a less proportion of net bank credit to the<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> sector.<br />

76


The positive coefficient of ACSCOP rejects the assumption th<strong>at</strong><br />

commercial banks are required to follow the policy of mutual<br />

substitutability with co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive institutions In the field of<br />

agricultural credit. Contrary to this, the positive coefficient implies the<br />

mutual complementary rel<strong>at</strong>ionship between the two sources of<br />

• agricultural credit. In other words, the commercial banks envisage the<br />

agricultural credit policy by strengthening the supply of credit where<br />

co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives are weak. This is also corrobor<strong>at</strong>ing with the findings<br />

th<strong>at</strong> of increasing share of commercial banks <strong>and</strong> RRB in the supply<br />

of total agricultural credit. However, this coefficient is surprisingly not<br />

significant.<br />

Conclusions<br />

This chapter analysed the trends in credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> by SCBs.<br />

The analysis brought out th<strong>at</strong> the proportion of credit flow to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> had significantly declined during the last one decade.<br />

Such a decline was more prominent during the re<strong>for</strong>m years. Across<br />

the bank groups also, a similar decline was observed. In the case of<br />

co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives the situ<strong>at</strong>ion was grimmer. More importantly, despite<br />

the fact th<strong>at</strong> the lending targets were fixed, direct <strong>and</strong> indirect <strong>finance</strong><br />

was clubbed, interest r<strong>at</strong>es were deregul<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>and</strong> lending procedures<br />

in the credit delivery system were simplified, the banks could not<br />

achieve the targets set in the case of agricultural lending.<br />

The analysis shows th<strong>at</strong> the number of agricultural accounts in<br />

the credit limit of Rs.25,OOO <strong>and</strong> the amount of credit in this range<br />

declined during the re<strong>for</strong>m period. The analysis also shows th<strong>at</strong>,<br />

within <strong>agriculture</strong>, banks provided larger quantum more funds to<br />

activities earning more interest income. This seemed to be more<br />

77


prominent after the deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of lending r<strong>at</strong>e to ultim<strong>at</strong>e borrowers.<br />

The better-off farmers had larger access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit as compared<br />

to small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers. Importantly, despite the increasing<br />

consensus to extend credit facility to <strong>agriculture</strong>, in general, <strong>and</strong> small<br />

<strong>and</strong> marginal farmers, in particular, banks were unable to lend to<br />

those activities with high social return or those c<strong>at</strong>egory of<br />

creditworthy borrowers who had been traditionally marginalised in the<br />

credit market. This finding is also backed by Stiglitz's study in 1994.<br />

This raises the issue of wh<strong>at</strong> factors determine the supply of<br />

institutional credit, <strong>and</strong> access to institutional credit. While the first<br />

Issue is analysed in this chapter, the l<strong>at</strong>ter issue has been taken up<br />

<strong>for</strong> a detailed analysis in chapter VI with the help of household level<br />

d<strong>at</strong>a.<br />

Credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> was neg<strong>at</strong>ively associ<strong>at</strong>ed with<br />

Investment in government securities, credit subsidy <strong>and</strong> proportion of<br />

credit provided by the co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives. Credit supply to <strong>agriculture</strong> was<br />

positively associ<strong>at</strong>ed with rural bank branches. This implies the need<br />

to reconsider the policy suggestion of closing loss-making rural bank<br />

branches. If it is absolutely essential to close down the bank<br />

branches on consider<strong>at</strong>ions of profitability, altern<strong>at</strong>ives in terms of<br />

farmers' clubs, self-help groups, etc., it should be introduced, <strong>and</strong><br />

strengthened.<br />

The analysis shows th<strong>at</strong> increasing lending r<strong>at</strong>e reduces the<br />

credit supply to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector by institutional agencies. This<br />

leads to the policy implic<strong>at</strong>ion th<strong>at</strong> it may not be sound to increase the<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>e. Besides, banks cannot use the interest r<strong>at</strong>e as screening<br />

de\ise due to adverse selection problem. This is due to the fact th<strong>at</strong><br />

78


orrowers, willing to pay high interest r<strong>at</strong>es, may be less worried<br />

about repayment of the loan. In this context, given the in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

asymmetry, Stiglitz <strong>and</strong> Weiss (1981) shows th<strong>at</strong> a profit maximising<br />

bank will practice credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning <strong>and</strong> be reluctant to increase interest<br />

r<strong>at</strong>es in response to an excess dem<strong>and</strong>. Consequently, high-risk group<br />

of borrowers may be completely excluded from the market although<br />

their prospective investments offer a high-expected return. Since<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> is a risky activity where farmers face shocks to their<br />

mcome, it appears th<strong>at</strong> bankers in India have been practising a tight<br />

credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning process to select a borrower. Given these problems<br />

one of the basic questions is th<strong>at</strong> wh<strong>at</strong> makes certain households to<br />

access institutional credit while others cannot? This issue has been<br />

taken up in gre<strong>at</strong> detail \~'hi!e making the household level analysis.<br />

The calcul<strong>at</strong>ions on credit subsidy show th<strong>at</strong> the total amount<br />

of credit was increasing, although the credit subsidy per Rs. 100 of<br />

outst<strong>and</strong>ing loan declined during the re<strong>for</strong>m period. It is also found<br />

th<strong>at</strong> credit subsidy adversely affected the supply of agricultural credit.<br />

It is also noticed th<strong>at</strong> increasing lending r<strong>at</strong>e could not be an<br />

appropri<strong>at</strong>e measure to reduce the credit subsidy, since it adversely<br />

affected the supply of agricultural credit. In this context, it can be<br />

suggested th<strong>at</strong> reduction in the cost of lending in terms of either<br />

fmancial cost or transaction cost or risk cost or by any combin<strong>at</strong>ions<br />

of these three should be the prime objective of the financial<br />

institutions to reduce the burden of credit subsidy. This can be made<br />

possible by better quality of credit delivery system (timely <strong>and</strong><br />

adequ<strong>at</strong>e) <strong>and</strong> prompt repayment of loans.<br />

79


Chapter 4<br />

INSTITUTIONAL CREDIT TO AGRICULTURE: STATE AND<br />

DISTRICT LEVEL ANALYSIS<br />

Introduction<br />

In Chapter III, it is noted th<strong>at</strong> the proportion of credit disbursed to<br />

"griculture to total net bank credit significantly declined during the<br />

period 1992-2000. Further, despite th<strong>at</strong> lending targets were fixed,<br />

direct <strong>and</strong> indirect <strong>finance</strong> was clubbed, interest r<strong>at</strong>es were<br />

deregul<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>and</strong> lending procedures were simplified, the institutional<br />

1gencies could not meet the targets fixed in the case of agricultural<br />

IL'rtding. The discussion on distribution of loan accounts <strong>and</strong><br />

n:lOunts by size class of l<strong>and</strong>holdings in Chapter III suggests th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

bt'tter-off among the farmers were having larger access to the<br />

mstitutional credit as compared to small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers.<br />

1t~1portantly,<br />

despite the widespread consensus to extend credit facility<br />

t(l <strong>agriculture</strong>, in general, <strong>and</strong> small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers, in<br />

particular, the banks could not <strong>finance</strong> this sector with high social<br />

;'('turns <strong>and</strong> cover those c<strong>at</strong>egory of borrowers who were marginalised<br />

:n 1 he <strong>for</strong>mal rural credit market. Chapter III also makes it clear th<strong>at</strong><br />

;il~<br />

ll1stitutionallending agencies were giving more importance to non­<br />

,c;ncultural lending. Elsewhere, it is argued th<strong>at</strong> rel<strong>at</strong>ively backward<br />

, "~l'll1S had less access to institutional credit than the developed ones<br />

''


l!lfferences m the irrig<strong>at</strong>ion infrastructure, use of high-yielding<br />

larteties, fertiliser consumption, etc., is the decline in the credit 110\\·<br />

ll!1l<strong>for</strong>m across the st<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong> districts? Does the access to<br />

Illstitutional credit vary by size classes of the l<strong>and</strong>holdings across the<br />

!"l'gions? Is there any vari<strong>at</strong>ion in the supply of agricultural credit per<br />

:\t·ctare of gross cropped area across the st<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong> districts? Wh<strong>at</strong><br />

dre the activities (both <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> non-<strong>agriculture</strong>) <strong>for</strong> which<br />

Illstitutional credit has been disbursed? Wh<strong>at</strong> has determined the<br />

s,·ctoral distribution of institutional credit?<br />

R<strong>at</strong>ionale of St<strong>at</strong>e Selection <strong>and</strong> D<strong>at</strong>abase<br />

This chapter seeks to address the above questions by confining the<br />

.1:1alvsis to 14 major st<strong>at</strong>es. These st<strong>at</strong>~s Flrp· Andhra Pradesh, Bih3.r<br />

I undivided), Gujar<strong>at</strong>, Haryana, Karn<strong>at</strong>aka, Kerala, Madhya Pradesh<br />

IUlldivided), Maharashtra, Orissa, Punjab, Rajasthan, Tamil Nadu,<br />

littar Pradesh (undivided) <strong>and</strong> West Bengal. The r<strong>at</strong>ionale <strong>for</strong> the<br />

selection of these st<strong>at</strong>es is as follows: the 14 st<strong>at</strong>es account <strong>for</strong> 93 per<br />

cent of the popul<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> 91.5 per cent of the Net Domestic Product<br />

I\;DP) in the country (Rao et aZI999); second, these st<strong>at</strong>es accounted,<br />

lin an average, 84.7 per cent of the total deposits in Scheduled<br />

l. 'mmercial Banks (SCBs) including RRBs during the last twenty<br />

\[·"rs; <strong>and</strong> third, 95 per cent of the total agricultural credit provided<br />

1)\ seBs <strong>and</strong> RRBs went to these st<strong>at</strong>es 28 The hill st<strong>at</strong>es loc<strong>at</strong>ed in<br />

: :u:·1 h <strong>and</strong> north-eastern parts of India, considered as special c<strong>at</strong>egory<br />

SI,,·,l'S by the Planning Commission, have been excluded from the<br />

.iii.: lysis as there are significant differences between these st<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong><br />

."i,C1s in terms of principal sources of income. The important sources<br />

: ;; •. ". d<strong>at</strong>a have been obtained from Banking St<strong>at</strong>istics pubilshed by the Rill.<br />

Sl


of income m the hill st<strong>at</strong>es are government activities, as there has<br />

hardly been any manufacturing base (Rao et al 1999).<br />

The district level analysis has been done <strong>for</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e of Orissa<br />

because of its backward st<strong>at</strong>us. The Economic Survey of Orissa <strong>for</strong> the<br />

year 2000-01 notes with concern th<strong>at</strong> the Credit Deposit R<strong>at</strong>io 29 (CDR)<br />

m the st<strong>at</strong>e declined from 80.59 per cent in 1991 to 39.75 per cent in<br />

1999-2000, while per-bank branch popul<strong>at</strong>ion increased from 15,200<br />

to 16,300 during the same period. The reduced CDR may have<br />

adversely affected the credit flow to different sectors in the st<strong>at</strong>e<br />

economy. In this context, there is need to look into the actual flow of<br />

credit to different sectors in the st<strong>at</strong>e, in general, <strong>and</strong> to <strong>agriculture</strong>, in<br />

particular.<br />

The analysis in this Chapter is based on secondary d<strong>at</strong>a. For<br />

the analysis of trends in 14 major st<strong>at</strong>es, the d<strong>at</strong>a were collected from<br />

the Reports on Currency <strong>and</strong> Finance (RBI), Banking St<strong>at</strong>istics (RBI),<br />

Fertiliser St<strong>at</strong>istics (the Fertiliser Associ<strong>at</strong>ion of India), Indian<br />

Agricultural St<strong>at</strong>istics (Ministry of Agriculture, Government of India)<br />

<strong>and</strong> St<strong>at</strong>istical Abstract (Central St<strong>at</strong>istical Organis<strong>at</strong>ion, Department<br />

of St<strong>at</strong>istics <strong>and</strong> Programme Implement<strong>at</strong>ion, Government of India).<br />

For an analysis of trends in Orissa, d<strong>at</strong>a were collected from St<strong>at</strong>e<br />

Level Bankers' Committee Meetings (Agenda Notes) <strong>and</strong> Orissa<br />

Agricultural St<strong>at</strong>istics (Director<strong>at</strong>e of Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Food Production,<br />

Orissa, Bhubaneswar).<br />

29 The CDR in Orissa was well below the all India average of 57.05 per cent in 1999·<br />

2000. In th<strong>at</strong> year, the st<strong>at</strong>es with CDR higher than th<strong>at</strong> in Orissa were: Tamil<br />

l"adu (88.0%), Maharashtra (83.79%), Andhra Pradesh (63.60%), Karn<strong>at</strong>aka<br />

(61.01 %), Gujar<strong>at</strong> (49.85%), Madhya Pradesh (49.17%), Rajasthan (46.69%), West<br />

Bengal (45.17%) <strong>and</strong> Kerala (42.29%). This in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion was collected from RBI<br />

(2000)<br />

82


St<strong>at</strong>e-wise Flow of Agricultural Credit<br />

Table 4.1 provides the growth r<strong>at</strong>es on agricultural credit <strong>for</strong> the<br />

period 1981-2000 in 14 major st<strong>at</strong>es. It also provides growth r<strong>at</strong>es <strong>for</strong><br />

credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> total credit <strong>for</strong> two sub periods, viz., 1981-<br />

1991 <strong>and</strong> 1992-2000. Total credit (<strong>for</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> others) in all<br />

the 14 major st<strong>at</strong>es grew <strong>at</strong> the r<strong>at</strong>e of 15.3 per cent during 1981-<br />

2000. There have been temporal vari<strong>at</strong>ions; the growth r<strong>at</strong>e during<br />

the re<strong>for</strong>m period was higher than th<strong>at</strong> during the pre-re<strong>for</strong>m period.<br />

The p<strong>at</strong>tern of growth r<strong>at</strong>es in the case of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

\\'as, however, different. The credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> in 14 major st<strong>at</strong>es<br />

mcreased <strong>at</strong> an annual growth r<strong>at</strong>e of 12 per cent during the entire<br />

period. However, the growth r<strong>at</strong>l;' during the re<strong>for</strong>m period '.'fas less<br />

110.9 per cent) than th<strong>at</strong> during the pre-re<strong>for</strong>m period (15.2 per cent).<br />

This clearly shows th<strong>at</strong> the r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>at</strong> which credit was disbursed to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> slowed down during the re<strong>for</strong>m period.<br />

This p<strong>at</strong>tern can be observed m all the st<strong>at</strong>es, except Punjab<br />

<strong>and</strong> Maharashtra. A comparison of growth r<strong>at</strong>es of credit to<br />

dgriculture between pre- <strong>and</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m periods reveals th<strong>at</strong> most of the<br />

't<strong>at</strong>es registered higher growth r<strong>at</strong>es of credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

'iuring the pre-re<strong>for</strong>m period as compared to the l<strong>at</strong>er period.<br />

83


Table 4.1: St<strong>at</strong>e-wise Annual Average Growth R<strong>at</strong>es (%) of<br />

outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit by SCBs<br />

St<strong>at</strong>es 1981 - 1991 1992 - 2000 L-l_~81 ·2000 =:J<br />

_____ ~Agric_"Itu;-er ~TotaC --:-Agrlculture ~ 'fotal . Agriculture _ Total<br />

High Income St<strong>at</strong>es<br />

-----------r--------T"'- - -- --- - - ----------<br />

l,ular<strong>at</strong> . __ ' 14. 7 ' 16.~ --"- __ 7-,~._~ J6,Q _._<br />

1I";"an';' 14. 3 , 14.9: 9. 3 14. 7<br />

~ ________-t______---t______ "____ - - -;- ____ .. _<br />

\lriharas_htr"--___· __ I:3.:!l.. i 13,---5_~_ 13. 9n_~11l, 9 __<br />

!'unjab _ -.-----i--I()~ 2..---+_-'1:JLJ __ ---'~ 7 ___ " .14..c S. _ .. _<br />

l;roupTot"l~ 13. 0_--, .. 14._0_ ~._ 10. 2 _--,-..l7..:~~_<br />

12.4<br />

9. 9<br />

12. 2<br />

15. 4<br />

13. °<br />

16. 2<br />

9. 2 13. I<br />

11. ° IS. 5<br />

- -- - ------<br />

_____ ._ -:-_--:-::--::--"M:::: idd1e_!nco-",_e. Sta t.e~ ___ --=----c -c-c-<br />

,\ndhra Pradesh I 13. 5 _!---,1,-,7.:.--.9 I 12. 2 . IS. 3, 11. 4 15.9!<br />

Karn<strong>at</strong>aka 17. ° 16. 6 13.~-17.-7-!-13. 0-=::::15.]:<br />

Kerala I, 15.2 14.8 j 12.6 i 16. l' 12. 1 __ 14 .._1_,<br />

Temil Nad-"u.~_--+ ____ 1=7'-.. cc3_-+--cl-':c7'-.. cc6_t-i' ____ 1--=0-'-. --=3_-,-1 17. 2: 13. 2 16. 7<br />

West Bengal I 17.5 14.5 I 3.5 '11.5-1 10.1--13.:'3-- 1<br />

GrouI' Iotal , 15.9 16. 4_--.l __'1~__!_'5:_Lj=-::::12:-2--15-:'3:::::;<br />

Low Income St<strong>at</strong>es<br />

i3,har- ==-_---,---:'-::6:-;2:--,-----"";15 9 ----43--, -107-' --11 2_-=X3 . .§_J<br />

\hdh.:·a Pradesh; 19.2 20.8 I 12. 5-------l--c)!;~_!_._14'-L ___ I§:_3_<br />

Onssa I 15.9 20. 7! 9.9 i II. 5 I 10. I . li-,--:?--j<br />

Rd.ja~han i 16.1 lS8 1').2 15.6 12.7 l-r.:1<br />

, ---,<br />

Uttar Pradesh I 15. ° 16. 8 I 9.8 i II. 8 I 12. 8 14. 3<br />

,-"oupTotal ! 16.3 17.6, 10. ° I 13. ° , I 12.7 14. ?J<br />

~ll MilJor St<strong>at</strong>es 15.2 15.7 i 10.~9~c'_'---;I§. ...9...--E:-O-_-- IS. 3 '<br />

Source: Reserve Bank of India (various issues of Banking St<strong>at</strong>istics from 1981 to<br />

2UOOI·<br />

We have c<strong>at</strong>egorised the 14 major st<strong>at</strong>es into high, middle <strong>and</strong><br />

low-income groups on the basis of net st<strong>at</strong>e domestic product. A<br />

comparison of growth r<strong>at</strong>es across different c<strong>at</strong>egories of st<strong>at</strong>es shows<br />

th<strong>at</strong> the growth r<strong>at</strong>es of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> in 1980s were higher <strong>for</strong><br />

!niddle <strong>and</strong> low-income st<strong>at</strong>es as compared to the high-income<br />

C dtegory of st<strong>at</strong>es (Table 4.1). In the case of st<strong>at</strong>es such as Bihar,<br />

;~ci]asthan,<br />

West Bengal, Kerala, Karn<strong>at</strong>aka, <strong>and</strong> Maharashtra, the<br />

t;r')\\'th r<strong>at</strong>e of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> was higher than th<strong>at</strong> to all sectors<br />

(i U ring the period 1981-91.<br />

However, the growth r<strong>at</strong>es of agricultural credit were much<br />

b'lo\\' than those in the case of total credit <strong>for</strong> all the st<strong>at</strong>es during the<br />

P,rtod 1992·2000. The growth r<strong>at</strong>es of credit to all the sectors <strong>and</strong> to<br />

8-1


<strong>agriculture</strong> declined during this period in the case of middle <strong>and</strong> lowincome<br />

st<strong>at</strong>es. But the decline in growth r<strong>at</strong>es was steep in the case of<br />

agricultural credit, especially in the case of Bihar, West Bengal <strong>and</strong><br />

c,<br />

Gujar<strong>at</strong>. In the case of high income group st<strong>at</strong>es, although the growth<br />

r<strong>at</strong>e of credit to all sectors increased during 1991-2000, it decreased<br />

in the case of <strong>agriculture</strong>. Thus, growth r<strong>at</strong>es of agricultural credit<br />

were uneven across the sub-periods as well as across the st<strong>at</strong>es.<br />

Wh<strong>at</strong> are the trends in the proportion of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

from SeBs <strong>for</strong> all the st<strong>at</strong>es? Table 4.2 provides the proportions of<br />

credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> to total net bank credit <strong>for</strong> four five-year periods<br />

beginning with 1981-85. In 1980s, the proportion of farm credit to<br />

total net bank credit was around 18 per cent of the total credit in all<br />

the major st<strong>at</strong>es. Thus, the institutional agencies were meeting the<br />

target of 18 per cent fixed under the priority sector lending norms. In<br />

nine out of 14 st<strong>at</strong>es, the priority sector norms were met during the<br />

period 1981-85.<br />

The number of st<strong>at</strong>es meeting the priority sector<br />

norms increased to 10 during the period 1986-90. In general, all the<br />

low-income st<strong>at</strong>es, <strong>and</strong> most of the middle income st<strong>at</strong>es were meeting<br />

the norms in 1980s.<br />

There was perceptible change in the level of credit provided to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> during 1990s. First, the proportion of farm credit to total<br />

net bank credit in all the 14 major st<strong>at</strong>es declined from 14.7 per cent<br />

during 1991-95 to 11.7 during the period 1996-2000. However, the<br />

proportion of agricultural credit in the total bank credit progressively<br />

declined to about 11.7 per cent during the period 1996-2000. Such a<br />

decline was uni<strong>for</strong>m across the st<strong>at</strong>es. Nevertheless, the priority sector<br />

norms in rel<strong>at</strong>ion to agricultural lending were met in nine <strong>and</strong> eight<br />

85


86<br />

st<strong>at</strong>es during 1991-95 <strong>and</strong> 1996-2000, respectively. Further, the<br />

norms were met in all the low-income st<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong> a few high <strong>and</strong><br />

middle-income st<strong>at</strong>es during 1996-2000. It has to be, however, noted<br />

th<strong>at</strong> if the proportion of net bank credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> in a particular<br />

st<strong>at</strong>e is more, th<strong>at</strong> does not necessarily mean th<strong>at</strong> credit per hectare of<br />

t.;ross cropped area is more. This implies th<strong>at</strong> on the basis of<br />

proportions of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> it may be difficult to conclude th<strong>at</strong><br />

a particular st<strong>at</strong>e is better-off in terms of amount of credit to<br />

agricultural sector. There<strong>for</strong>e, the <strong>for</strong>mal credit available per hectare<br />

of gross cropped area can be a better indic<strong>at</strong>or to explain the<br />

agricultural credit situ<strong>at</strong>ion in a particular st<strong>at</strong>e. We have, there<strong>for</strong>e,<br />

taken the supply of credit per hectare of gross cropped area <strong>at</strong> the<br />

st<strong>at</strong>e level as the dependent variable in the<br />

contributing to vari<strong>at</strong>ions in the supply of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> in<br />

Section 4.5.<br />

The trends in the proportion of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> during the<br />

last two decades, thus, suggest th<strong>at</strong> the following factors have<br />

influenced the overall figures <strong>for</strong> 14 st<strong>at</strong>es. First, the low proportion<br />

of agricultural credit in the industrialised st<strong>at</strong>es of Maharashtra,<br />

Gujar<strong>at</strong>, West Bengal <strong>and</strong> Tamil Nadu has had substantial influence<br />

on the overall figures. In the case of West Bengal <strong>and</strong> Maharashtra,<br />

the priority sector norms were not met even during both pre-re<strong>for</strong>m<br />

periods. Second, the low proportion of agricultural credit could be<br />

<strong>at</strong>tributed to a low growth r<strong>at</strong>e of agricultural credit compared to the<br />

total credit in all the st<strong>at</strong>es especially during the re<strong>for</strong>m period. This<br />

shows th<strong>at</strong> bankers were giving priority to non-agricultural lending in<br />

almost all the st<strong>at</strong>es.


00<br />

Table 4.2: St<strong>at</strong>e-wise Agricultural Sector Lending (%) to Total<br />

Credit <strong>and</strong> Total Deposit<br />

St<strong>at</strong>es<br />

(II\lar<strong>at</strong><br />

ii. lr\-ana<br />

\1 ailarashtra<br />

nlab<br />

Qun Total<br />

:rlhra Pradesh<br />

l:-n<strong>at</strong>aka<br />

'rala<br />

Ta mll Nadu<br />

,'st Bengal<br />

; 11! 'oup Total<br />

8: har<br />

adhya Pradesh<br />

U nssa<br />

Ra Jasthan<br />

.tar Pradesh<br />

-uup Total<br />

, AI I ~laJor St<strong>at</strong>es<br />

Average <strong>for</strong> the<br />

Period of<br />

Average <strong>for</strong> the<br />

Period of<br />

1981-85 1986-90<br />

ACHC I ACHD ACHC ACHD<br />

High Income St<strong>at</strong>es<br />

15. 2 B. 0 14. 4 B. 4<br />

31. 3 29. 1 28. 5 22.7<br />

6. 4 5. 5 7.3 4.8<br />

33. 4 19.5 28. 3 12.6<br />

13. 0 9. 7 12.7 7.9<br />

Middle Income St<strong>at</strong>e.<br />

35. 7 25. 7 29.5 23. 1<br />

23. 2 18.4 24. 3 20.9<br />

17.5 11.5 lB.3 II. 8<br />

16.9 14.5 17.4 16. 3<br />

7. 1 3. 3 9. 7 4.8<br />

19.5 13. 0 19.6 14. I<br />

Low Income St<strong>at</strong>es<br />

24.5 9. 2 25. 7 8. 8<br />

Average <strong>for</strong><br />

the Period of<br />

I Average <strong>for</strong><br />

the Period of<br />

1991-95 1996-2000<br />

ACHC I ACHD I ACHC I ACBD<br />

14. 1 7. 6 9 9 5. 4<br />

25. 0 16. 0 19. 2 10. 4<br />

5. 0 3. 0 4. 1 3. 1<br />

22. B 10. 1 lB. 6 7. 6<br />

9.6 5. 6 7. 1 4.6<br />

22. 6 17. 5 19.7 14. I<br />

20. B 14. 6 16. 9 II. 6<br />

15. 8 7. 6 13. 5 5.9<br />

14. 1 12. 4 10. 7 9. B<br />

6. 5 3. 3 4. B 2. 2<br />

15. 6 10.4 13. 0 8. 4<br />

25. 7 9. 7 19. B 5. 4<br />

",.... ~<br />

~.t:.. J<br />

, 13.4 i 9. 5 10. I<br />

20. 7 13. 4 19.0 9. 0<br />

25. a 13.9 21. 3 10.5<br />

21. 8 9. 2 19.5 6. 3<br />

23. a 10. 9 19.8 7. 6<br />

14. 7 8. 6 II. 7 6. B<br />

~\,)tc. ACBe - Agncultural sector credit as a proportIon to net bank credit.<br />

ACBD = Agricultural sector credit as a proportion to total bank deposit.<br />

Source: Reserve Bank of India (various issues of Banking St<strong>at</strong>istics from the year 1981 to<br />

2000).<br />

Let US now turn our <strong>at</strong>tention to the discussion on trends in<br />

.\gricultural Sector Credit as a proportion to the total bank deposit<br />

l/leBD). This indic<strong>at</strong>es the extent to which the deposits mobilised in a<br />

Sidle were lent to agricultural sector. The key findings emerging from<br />

dll analysis of trends in ACBD in 14 st<strong>at</strong>es put together, <strong>and</strong> in<br />

IIldl\"ldual st<strong>at</strong>es are the following:<br />

• During the period 1981 to 2000, ACBD declined progressively in all<br />

l.~le<br />

14 major st<strong>at</strong>es taken together.<br />

• There was also a decline in ACBD in the individual st<strong>at</strong>es except in<br />

the case of a few st<strong>at</strong>es during 1986-90.<br />

87


88<br />

There were substantial inter-st<strong>at</strong>e differences in ACBD in one subperiod<br />

as well as between four sub-periods. The poorer st<strong>at</strong>es such<br />

as Bihar <strong>and</strong> Uttar Pradesh had lower ACBD all through the period<br />

of 1981-2000 <strong>and</strong> even during the period 1981-85. In<br />

agriculturally prosperous st<strong>at</strong>e of Haryana, the ACBD was high <strong>for</strong><br />

most part of the last two decades. The situ<strong>at</strong>ion in Bihar <strong>and</strong> Uttar<br />

Pradesh in terms of ACBD was even worse during the period 1996-<br />

2000. In Bihar, ACBD dropped from 9.2 to 5.4 per cent during the<br />

period 1981-2000, while in Uttar Pradesh it declined from 10.1 to<br />

6.3 per cent during the same period. Interestingly, among 14 major<br />

st<strong>at</strong>es, it was West Bengal, a middle income st<strong>at</strong>e, which had the<br />

distinction of having the lowest ACBD throughout the last two<br />

decades.<br />

The gap between proportion of agricultural credit to total net bank<br />

credit (ACBC) <strong>and</strong> ACBD was generally large in the poorer st<strong>at</strong>es as<br />

compared to the agriculturally prosperous st<strong>at</strong>es. For instance, the<br />

gap between these two was as high as 15.3 <strong>and</strong> 14.1 in Bihar <strong>and</strong><br />

Uttar Pradesh, respectively, as compared to only 2.2 in Haryana<br />

during the period 1981-1985.<br />

It can be also seen th<strong>at</strong> ACBD was less than ACBC in all the 14<br />

st<strong>at</strong>es during all time periods. A constant decline in the ACBD in<br />

all the major st<strong>at</strong>es indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> banks have been diverting their<br />

funds to other than agricultural sector. Such a diversion seems to<br />

be more prominent in the backward st<strong>at</strong>es like Bihar, Uttar<br />

Pradesh, <strong>and</strong> West Bengal.<br />

The extent of diversion of funds out of deposits mobilised was<br />

equally high in developed st<strong>at</strong>es of Maharashtra, Kerala, <strong>and</strong>


Gujar<strong>at</strong>. This implies th<strong>at</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> in a st<strong>at</strong>e belonging to a<br />

high-income c<strong>at</strong>egory need not necessarily receive higher priority in<br />

terms of alloc<strong>at</strong>ion of credit. Thus, the income st<strong>at</strong>us of the st<strong>at</strong>e<br />

(per capita income in this case) itself does not determine the supply<br />

of agricultural credit. We presume th<strong>at</strong> supply side factors<br />

determine the level of credit made available to agricultural sector.<br />

Such a presumption is borne out by the fact th<strong>at</strong> the high per<br />

capita income in a particular st<strong>at</strong>e need not necessarily be due to<br />

high agricultural income. The non-agricultural sectors may have<br />

played an important role in the level of per capita income. If this is<br />

the case, the bankers may give priority to non-agricultural sectors<br />

in their lending portfolio purely on the grounds of profitability.<br />

Since the proportion of agricultural credit to net b~.nk credit has<br />

been declining over a period of time, it can be suggested th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

bankers may not be considering lending to agricultural sector as<br />

profitable.<br />

In the all India level analysis, we found th<strong>at</strong> the proportion of<br />

investment in government <strong>and</strong> other approved securities from total<br />

bank deposits, interest r<strong>at</strong>e, <strong>and</strong> credit subsidy were the important<br />

itctors th<strong>at</strong> were adversely affecting the supply of agricultural credit.<br />

Smce the same type of d<strong>at</strong>a is not available <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level, we have<br />

used st<strong>at</strong>e's characteristics 30 to examine the supply of agricultural<br />

credit.<br />

'.'<br />

30 I t includes the percentage of irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area to gross cropped area, area under<br />

commercial crops to gross cropped area, credit deposit r<strong>at</strong>io, <strong>and</strong> density of bank<br />

branches per 1,000 farmers.<br />

89


Distribution P<strong>at</strong>tern of Agricultural Credit<br />

The discussion on trends in the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> with the help<br />

of growth <strong>and</strong> level of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> leads us to the following<br />

conclusions. First, there was a rapid growth of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> in<br />

(he 1980s. Such a rapid flow was generally <strong>at</strong>tributed to the supply­<br />

Jed approach adopted by the <strong>for</strong>mal institutional agencies (Adams <strong>and</strong><br />

Vogel 1986; Gadgil 1994; Shajahan 1999; Kohli 1999; Shivamagi<br />

2000). Second, the fall-out of such an approach could be considered<br />

as the contributing factor <strong>for</strong> the decline in the credit flow to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> in the 1990s. The liter<strong>at</strong>ure suggests th<strong>at</strong> a preoccup<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

to achieve quantit<strong>at</strong>ive targets in 1980s ignoring the qualit<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

aspects resulted in high cost structure of oper<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> mounting<br />

overdues within the banking system. This hec:ame a thre<strong>at</strong> to the<br />

VIability of the financial institutions. As noted earlier, the introduction<br />

of policies rel<strong>at</strong>ing to market-oriented <strong>and</strong> competitive financial<br />

system since 1991 aimed to improve the viability of the financial<br />

institutions. Although the target of agricultural credit was kept the<br />

same during the 1990s, there was a decline in the credit to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>. This, perhaps, could be because of credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning<br />

practices. As was found in the review of liter<strong>at</strong>ure in Chapter 2, the<br />

perceptions on risks involved in agricultural lending, the banks might<br />

be <strong>for</strong>ced to adopt price <strong>and</strong> non-price credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning to increase the<br />

efficiency <strong>and</strong> viability of financial institutions in the provisioning of<br />

agricultural credit. In order to see whether bankers have adopted price<br />

<strong>and</strong> non-price credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning in the alloc<strong>at</strong>ion of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong>,<br />

there is need to examine the access of credit to different c<strong>at</strong>egories of<br />

farmers. For this purpose, the d<strong>at</strong>a on the distribution of credit by<br />

dIfferent size-classes of l<strong>and</strong>holdings have been examined in this<br />

scctlon.<br />

90


Access to credit has been defined as the number of farmers<br />

obtaining <strong>for</strong>mal credit to total farmers in a st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>at</strong> a particular point<br />

of time. For the analysis of distribution of credit by size-classes of<br />

l<strong>and</strong>holdings, we have relied upon the d<strong>at</strong>a on oper<strong>at</strong>ional holdings<br />

provided in quinquenial agricultural census. As per the l<strong>at</strong>est<br />

published agricultural census d<strong>at</strong>a, st<strong>at</strong>e-wise number of oper<strong>at</strong>ional<br />

holdings are available only <strong>for</strong> the years 1980-81, 1985-86 <strong>and</strong> 1990-<br />

91. The d<strong>at</strong>a on the total number of holdings in each st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> these<br />

time-points have been used to examine the access to credit (Direct<br />

Finance to Farmers) by different c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers. However, <strong>for</strong><br />

the year 1996-97, the number of farmers (oper<strong>at</strong>ional holdings) has<br />

been calcul<strong>at</strong>ed by the extrapol<strong>at</strong>ion method 31 . Since st<strong>at</strong>e-wise<br />

number of accounts on direct fmance is available up to 1996-97, we<br />

have calcul<strong>at</strong>ed the number of farmers <strong>for</strong> the l<strong>at</strong>est year to examine<br />

the position of access to credit. The st<strong>at</strong>e-wise number of outst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

loan accounts on direct <strong>finance</strong> has been taken into account <strong>for</strong> the<br />

analysis. The d<strong>at</strong>a on number of loan accounts have been obtained<br />

from the Reports on Currency <strong>and</strong> Finance, <strong>and</strong> number of farmers<br />

from Fertiliser St<strong>at</strong>istics.<br />

The distribution of agricultural credit <strong>at</strong> the all India level shows<br />

th<strong>at</strong> the farmers with more than 2 ha of oper<strong>at</strong>ional holding were<br />

having larger access to the <strong>for</strong>mal credit as compared to those with<br />

less than 2 ha (small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers) (Table 4.3). The same<br />

:rend could also be observed <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level. There were substantial<br />

lIlter-st<strong>at</strong>e differences in the access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit by the same<br />

, cltegory of farmers <strong>at</strong> one time point as well as between different time<br />

, .--------------------<br />

~<br />

The number of fanners in the current year (y,) = Yo (1 ... r) t, where Yo st<strong>and</strong>s <strong>for</strong><br />

number of farmers in the base year, r st<strong>and</strong>s <strong>for</strong> r<strong>at</strong>e of growth, t represents time<br />

penods, <strong>and</strong> r = (Yt/ Yo)'/' - 1.<br />

91


ihllnts. The access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit by the small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers<br />

ilCld gone down in the year 1996-97 as compared to 1990-91 in all the<br />

,Lites except Gujar<strong>at</strong>. Among the st<strong>at</strong>es, the proportion of marginal<br />

,me! small farmers having access to institutional credit was the<br />

:li."hest in Punjab (26.7 per cent) In 1996-97 followed by Tamil Nadu<br />

,JlHI Andhra Pradesh. However, In the st<strong>at</strong>es like Bihar, Madhya<br />

Pradesh, Uttar Pradesh, Haryana, <strong>and</strong> Maharashtra only 5 to 6.7 per<br />

c,~nt<br />

of the marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers were having access to <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

credit in the same year. For farmers with more than 2 ha. of<br />

(,ptT<strong>at</strong>ional holdings (medium <strong>and</strong> large), 63.2 per cent of them were<br />

we-essing <strong>for</strong>mal credit in Tamil Nadu followed by Kerala (45 %), <strong>and</strong><br />

Punjab (31.6 %) in 1996-97. The percentage of medium <strong>and</strong> large<br />

f8rmers having access to institutional credit was substantially less in<br />

the st<strong>at</strong>es like Madhya Pradesh, Rajasthan <strong>and</strong> Maharashtra. It can<br />

be. there<strong>for</strong>e, concluded th<strong>at</strong> even the same size of l<strong>and</strong>holdings were<br />

h,i\'ing uneven access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit across the st<strong>at</strong>es. This finding<br />

holds good <strong>for</strong> all sizes of farmers. In this context, it is necessary to<br />

examine wh<strong>at</strong> factors contribute to some fann households to access<br />

(annal credit, while others do not. Since this question cannot be<br />

111S\\cred with the help of st<strong>at</strong>e level analysis due to non-availability of<br />

ij,lid. this question is taken up <strong>for</strong> analysis <strong>at</strong> the household level.<br />

The outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit (direct <strong>finance</strong> 32 ) per loan account varies<br />

·.'.,;I,in <strong>and</strong> across different c<strong>at</strong>egories of st<strong>at</strong>es <strong>at</strong> one time point as<br />

Ilie direct <strong>finance</strong> covers both short-term <strong>and</strong> long-term loans. Short-term loans<br />

!::kluding crop loans) are given <strong>for</strong> the purchase of production inputs, such as,<br />

sPc·ds. fertiliser, pesticides, etc., <strong>and</strong> to meet the cost of cultiv<strong>at</strong>ion, which<br />

i::, 'eldes labour charges <strong>for</strong> carrying out agricultural oper<strong>at</strong>ions, irrig<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

'Cl..rgCS. etc. Term (medium/long) loans are granted <strong>for</strong> development purposes<br />

",,>, development of irrig<strong>at</strong>ion potential, purchase of tractors <strong>and</strong> other<br />

,"::cultural implements <strong>and</strong> machmery, improvement of l<strong>and</strong>, development of<br />

,\!.",t<strong>at</strong>lOns, construction of godowns <strong>and</strong> cold storages, purchase of pump<br />

v·:s oil engines, plough animals (bullocks). etc.


well as between different time points. The amount of credit per loan<br />

account was higher in the st<strong>at</strong>es belonging to high-income c<strong>at</strong>egory as<br />

compared to those in the middle <strong>and</strong> low-income c<strong>at</strong>egories. On an<br />

average, small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers in Haryana obtained Rs.22,181<br />

of credit per loan account in 1996-97. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, farmers<br />

belonging to the same size of oper<strong>at</strong>ional holding in Orissa obtained<br />

only Rs.4,862 per loan account. Such vari<strong>at</strong>ions can be found even<br />

among medium <strong>and</strong> large farmers in so far as the amount of credit<br />

obtained per loan account across the st<strong>at</strong>es.<br />

Table 4.3: St<strong>at</strong>e-wise <strong>and</strong> Size Class-wise Access to Direct<br />

Finance by the Farmers<br />

_____ !inEer. cefl!L<br />

St<strong>at</strong>es i Up to 2 Hectares I Above 2 Hectares .. '<br />

~980-8111985-861199.q:91119J16-97 L!980-8111985-86,i990~9111996~~'[<br />

5. 6<br />

High Income St<strong>at</strong>es<br />

- - ---r<br />

13. 5-- 12.9 14. 1 i 6. 4<br />

7. 2 11. 6 11. 2 5. 0 11. 6<br />

3.6 7.4 9. 4 6. 7 5. 4<br />

21. 5 38. 0 41. 2 26. 7 22. 7<br />

5.6 11. 1 12. 0 8. 8 8. 0<br />

G uj,ar<strong>at</strong><br />

H aryana<br />

M aharashtra<br />

Pu njab<br />

G rouo Total<br />

_ ~ ___---,,--,~-=----.--=-~:;--Mr=',ddle Income St<strong>at</strong>es<br />

Andhra 16.0 24. 7 23. 3 20.1! 16. 3<br />

Pradesh<br />

Karn<strong>at</strong>aka 11.3 20.9 19.1 11.3 9.2<br />

Kerala 15.0 21.0 17.6 15.5 21.3<br />

Tamil Nadu 11. 8 19.6 25.8 20. 3 11. 7<br />

West Bengal 7. 4 12. 9 12. 0 10. 8 I 9. 2<br />

Grall]) Total 12.3 19.8 20. 1 16.3 12.6<br />

Low-InC"O-me St<strong>at</strong>es<br />

-<br />

Alh ar<br />

Ma dhya<br />

Pra desh<br />

3. 6 5.6<br />

4. 0 7. 7<br />

6. 7 5. 0 5. 7<br />

9. 3 5. 8 I 6. 0<br />

IB.4 14. 4 9. 7<br />

12.4 B. 2 4. 4<br />

6. 3 5. 2 11. 3<br />

I<br />

14. 4 I 17.5 I 10.6<br />

17.7 i 18. 7 11. 4<br />

10.7 I 12. 0 9. 1<br />

29. 7 , 42. 2 31. 6<br />

I 14.2 I 17.0<br />

i<br />

11. 8<br />

I<br />

.-----<br />

23_6 , 21. 9 i 24. 5 ~<br />

15.7 I<br />

51. 2 :<br />

24_ 5 :<br />

11. 5 I<br />

20. 5 I<br />

11. 0 I<br />

,<br />

7. 2<br />

,<br />

I<br />

I<br />

,<br />

I<br />

16.4 i<br />

45.0 I<br />

44.9 :<br />

12.4 I<br />

23.2 I<br />

11. 7 ,<br />

8. 0<br />

,<br />

,<br />

15. 8 '<br />

45. 0<br />

63. 2<br />

17. 1 '<br />

30. 5 -,<br />

11. 6<br />

7. 1<br />

Or lssa 8. 3 16. 2<br />

11. 7 I 11. 7<br />

,<br />

20. 2<br />

Raj asthan 3. 3 9. B<br />

6. 8 I 6.~ ___ 5. 0_<br />

,<br />

Cit ar<br />

3. 3 5. 5<br />

lB. 2<br />

I 21. 4 I IB.9<br />

Pra desh<br />

I ,<br />

:<br />

i --~.<br />

Gr oup Total 3. 8 6.9 B. 1 6. 2 7. I 10. 4 11. 3 I 10.3<br />

"ole: FIgures on the number of accounts <strong>for</strong> all the years have been gIven <strong>for</strong> the<br />

period July-June except <strong>for</strong> the year 1980-81 (April to March).<br />

Sources: 1) Reserve Bank of India (Report on Currency <strong>and</strong> Finance, Vol. 11, <strong>for</strong> the<br />

year 1982-83, 1987-88, 1992-93, <strong>and</strong> 1997-98).<br />

2) Fertiliser Associ<strong>at</strong>ion of India, New Delhi, 1999-2000 (Fertiliser<br />

St<strong>at</strong>istics)_<br />

93


8,557LlI,I<br />

Table 4.4: St<strong>at</strong>e-wise <strong>and</strong> Size Class-wise Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit<br />

(Direct Finance to Farmers) Per Loan Account<br />

St<strong>at</strong>es 1 . .,!1p to 2 Hectares ' Above 2He~'i;.~:tesl. --_.<br />

Gujar <strong>at</strong><br />

HaI}'a na<br />

~laha rashtra<br />

l'unja b<br />

GrollI'. Total<br />

-<br />

,\nd hra<br />

Pra desh<br />

Kar n<strong>at</strong>aka<br />

Ker ala<br />

Tam il Nadu<br />

We st8_enga1<br />

Gro up Total<br />

[19S0-S1 j19S5-S6 , 1999~9 ,!,;_1J196:97_19_80-S.b _l!I_S5-8~ L!i!lQ~91Jl9.96-97_<br />

3,145<br />

High Income St<strong>at</strong>es<br />

- -----<br />

48901 7, 1621 16,773: 9,3891 14,iI49117,4741 -2?~i2_~<br />

2,938 5,7821 10,8001 22,1811 17,779: 20,8221 39,0771 72,228<br />

I<br />

3,280 5,663 7823 1 13,118<br />

1<br />

~H,8 39' 33.330<br />

2,940 10,511 99271 21 7571 15,0671 18,.f=~ 28,3_ 63: 57,154<br />

3 121 6,526 8,349: 15,95~!I,7821 14,705 22,10241-:-681<br />

Middle Income St<strong>at</strong>es<br />

1,913 3,430 5,540 9,492'1 4,2181 7,073 11,332: 17,648<br />

I ,<br />

i<br />

2,226 3,989 6,503 15,8791 6,665' 10,011 15,8081 33,451<br />

1500 2645 5,095 8,897\ 7,425\ 10,695 16066\ 8,771<br />

1,860 :t.505 5552 12,891 1 6,280 9,097 12,649' 19,857<br />

1577 1922 2,859 6595\ 8430' 24,813 23,448 44,562<br />

1800 3,172 5,278 1O,675! 5611\ 9,526 13,655 21,341<br />

Low Income St<strong>at</strong>es<br />

1598 2581 3922 5550 6,688 6,951 20,315 26,471<br />

3,051 4,071 7,937 10,960 5,416 10,099: 21,358 1 36,429<br />

i<br />

1,359 2.,.877 2,875 4,862 1,664 4,070' 8,490 8,535<br />

2874 3430 5405 8969 8244 15,801 27,881 47,733<br />

1603 ~197 5327 8,436 7733 10,552 16,895 32,096<br />

1786 3136 4938 7481 63731 10,172 193821 31,023<br />

81ha r<br />

Mon hy;::t<br />

Prad esh<br />

Ons sa<br />

.RaJa sthan<br />

- -<br />

etta r Pradesh<br />

Gro \IP Total<br />

Source: Reserve Bank of IndIa (Report on Currency <strong>and</strong> Fmance, Vol. II, <strong>for</strong> the years<br />

1982-83, 1987-88, 1992-93, <strong>and</strong> 1997-98).<br />

One important finding from Tables 4.3 <strong>and</strong> 4.4 is th<strong>at</strong> while the<br />

percentage of farmers accessing <strong>for</strong>mal credit during 1990s was<br />

declining in most of the st<strong>at</strong>es, the loan amount per account kept on<br />

increasing. This implies th<strong>at</strong> there was concentr<strong>at</strong>ion of <strong>for</strong>mal loan in<br />

favour of a particular group of borrowers, <strong>and</strong> th<strong>at</strong> the banks<br />

practised both price <strong>and</strong> non-price credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning methods in the<br />

borrower selection <strong>and</strong> fix<strong>at</strong>ion of the credit limit. This is further<br />

corrobor<strong>at</strong>ed by the fact th<strong>at</strong> farmers within the same size-class of<br />

l<strong>and</strong>holding obtained substantially different loan amounts across the<br />

st<strong>at</strong>es. In this context, it is essential to examine wh<strong>at</strong> made some<br />

farmers to obtain more credit from <strong>for</strong>mal sector even when they fell<br />

under the same c<strong>at</strong>egory of holding. In other words, how did the<br />

94


95<br />

bankers fIx the credit limit <strong>for</strong> different c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers? Since<br />

the d<strong>at</strong>a on characteristics of farmers accessing credit are not<br />

available <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level, factors determining the amount of credit <strong>at</strong><br />

the household level have been taken up <strong>for</strong> discussion in Chapter VI.<br />

However, an <strong>at</strong>tempt has been made in this chapter to analyse<br />

the vari<strong>at</strong>ions in <strong>for</strong>mal credit per hectare of gross cropped area. At<br />

this stage, if we analyse the vari<strong>at</strong>ions of credit per loan account, then<br />

it may not represent the true position of agricultural credit In a<br />

particular st<strong>at</strong>e. Because, this kind of analysis <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level<br />

explains the credit widening (percentage of farmers with access to<br />

direct fInance), <strong>and</strong> does not shed much light on farm households<br />

which are out of <strong>for</strong>mal credit market. Against this backdrop, credit<br />

per hectare of gross cropped area seems more relevant. Furthermore,<br />

credit per hectare of gross cropped area takes into account<br />

autom<strong>at</strong>ically the obtained amount of credit by the farmers. Thus,<br />

higher the percentage of farmers accessing <strong>for</strong>mal credit, higher will<br />

be the credit amount per hectare of gross cropped area.<br />

We have calcul<strong>at</strong>ed the amount of credit per hectare of gross<br />

cropped area in Table 4.5 to examine st<strong>at</strong>e-wise vari<strong>at</strong>ions. This<br />

analysis has been undertaken only <strong>for</strong> 1980-81, 1985-6 <strong>and</strong> 1990-91<br />

as the d<strong>at</strong>a on area under different size-classes of oper<strong>at</strong>ional holdings<br />

are available only <strong>for</strong> these time points. As in the case of the access<br />

<strong>and</strong> amount of credit obtained per loan account, there have been<br />

substantial inter-st<strong>at</strong>e differences in the amount of credit per hectare<br />

of oper<strong>at</strong>ional holding within <strong>and</strong> across different sizes of farmers<br />

(Table 4.5). Per hectare amount of credit obtained by farmers in lowincome<br />

c<strong>at</strong>egory st<strong>at</strong>es was less than th<strong>at</strong> obtained by the farmers<br />

from middle <strong>and</strong> high-income c<strong>at</strong>egory st<strong>at</strong>es. This holds good in the


96<br />

case of both c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers <strong>at</strong> all time points. For instance, the<br />

,werage credit per hectare of oper<strong>at</strong>ional holding in low-income<br />

c<strong>at</strong>egory st<strong>at</strong>es was Rs 659 <strong>for</strong> the farmer with holding up to 2<br />

hectares in 1990-91, whereas, it was Rs 4,161 in the case of Punjab,<br />

the high income st<strong>at</strong>e. In the case of other middle <strong>and</strong> high-income<br />

c<strong>at</strong>egory st<strong>at</strong>es like Kerala, Tamil Nadu, Andhra Pradesh, <strong>and</strong><br />

Haryana also per hectare credit was sufficiently higher than th<strong>at</strong> of<br />

low-income c<strong>at</strong>egory st<strong>at</strong>es <strong>at</strong> one as well as different points of time<br />

even <strong>for</strong> the same size of holdings.<br />

Table 4.5: St<strong>at</strong>e-wise <strong>and</strong> Size Class-wise Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit<br />

Per Hectare of Oper<strong>at</strong>ional Holding<br />

__ ~ __-r______ ~~~~~~ ________.-____ ~ ____ ~~ __ ~inRupees)<br />

St<strong>at</strong>es f---,--=-cc~~",=to~2 He;,c~ta""ir,..e,:,s===_If-:-:=~A~b-:o,,-,v,:,e=2 Hectares. ____ '<br />

____'--==-"--"=--'----'1'-"9-'::8~5-86 I 1990·91 11980-811 1985-86 199.0_-9_1_'<br />

Htdl. Incoft'le Sta+es<br />

Guja r<strong>at</strong><br />

HaT} 'ana 1<br />

Mah arashtra I<br />

Purl) ab<br />

Grou LP Total<br />

Andh ra<br />

Prade sh<br />

Karna taka<br />

Kerala<br />

Tamil Nadu<br />

\\est Bengal<br />

Group Total<br />

I<br />

I<br />

- -<br />

181 6811 928'<br />

231 842 1,478'<br />

132 443 791;<br />

629 4,115 4,161 '<br />

189 768 1071·<br />

MIddle<br />

.<br />

Income St<strong>at</strong>es<br />

406 1,160 1,7851<br />

i<br />

282 933 1,411 i<br />

784 1,995 3,7971<br />

377 1227 2,6071<br />

183 383 524j<br />

358 1,024<br />

1<br />

1,769<br />

Low Income St<strong>at</strong>es<br />

120 287 549)<br />

147 382 888i<br />

J<br />

137 590 6771<br />

110 389 775,<br />

95 326 594'<br />

108' 408 606<br />

330 691 1,491-<br />

89 247 456 ,<br />

618 924 2,08'!J<br />

174 409 789,<br />

141 i 355 5651<br />

,<br />

,<br />

,<br />

- -<br />

1151 315 560'<br />

~<br />

3931 1,267 1,612<br />

1731 528 1,39§.; "<br />

222, 840 824,<br />

1501 428: 7291<br />

B,har<br />

88: 188' 609',<br />

~ladh ya<br />

52 128 319', 1<br />

Prade sh<br />

1<br />

Onss a<br />

431 125 279~<br />

-------.<<br />

liajas than<br />

--- -<br />

461 141 257<br />

Lltar Pradesh<br />

220 504 972<br />

G~ou p Total 114 358 659 81, 197 42-2'<br />

oj<br />

'/ote: D<strong>at</strong>a on area under oper<strong>at</strong>ional holdmgs has been collected from the FertilIser<br />

Associ<strong>at</strong>ion of India, New Delhi, 1999-2000 (Fertiliser St<strong>at</strong>istics), <strong>and</strong><br />

corresponding loan amount <strong>for</strong> these c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers has been collected<br />

from the Reserve Bank India (Report on Currency <strong>and</strong> Finance, Vol-H) <strong>for</strong> the<br />

year 1982-83, 1987-88, <strong>and</strong> 1992-93.


Determinants of Credit Flow to Agriculture <strong>at</strong> the St<strong>at</strong>e Level<br />

It has been observed in Section 4.4 th<strong>at</strong> there were substantial inter­<br />

~'c<strong>at</strong>c<br />

differences in credit per loan account as well as per hectare of<br />

,lper<strong>at</strong>ional holding <strong>at</strong> one <strong>and</strong> different time points even <strong>for</strong> the same<br />

Size-class of l<strong>and</strong>holdings across st<strong>at</strong>esc Wh<strong>at</strong> explains these<br />

differences? This section takes up this questionc Be<strong>for</strong>e we go into the<br />

details of the analysis, two aspects need to be mentionedc First, since<br />

the d<strong>at</strong>a on characteristics of households obtaining <strong>for</strong>mal credit are<br />

not available <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>levels</strong>, the analysis on vari<strong>at</strong>ions in credit<br />

availability per loan account is quite difficulL Second, due to<br />

c1\Cailability of d<strong>at</strong>a on oper<strong>at</strong>ional holdings, which is confined to only<br />

three time points, a rigorous analysis is difficultc There<strong>for</strong>e, an<br />

<strong>at</strong>tempt has been made in this section to ~xamine the factors 'Nhich<br />

,'on tribute to the vari<strong>at</strong>ions in the amount of credit per hectare of<br />

c;ross cropped area. Hence, credit per hectare of gross cropped area<br />

,eGA) is the dependent variable in the analysis. The a priori model on<br />

1 he determinants of supply of agricultural credit has been specified<br />

\\Cith the following variables.<br />

1:/) Percentage of Irrig<strong>at</strong>ed Area to Gross Cropped Area (AIR33)<br />

From the supply side, flow of credit can be said to be depending<br />

upon the lender's assessment as regards the repayment capacity of<br />

the borrower. It is assumed th<strong>at</strong> irrig<strong>at</strong>ion facility can increase the<br />

level of production <strong>and</strong> in turn, the repayment of the loan.<br />

There<strong>for</strong>e, the percentage of irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area to gross cropped area<br />

3- To calcul<strong>at</strong>e AIR we have taken d<strong>at</strong>a from Indian Agricultural St<strong>at</strong>istics<br />

(Department of Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Co·oper<strong>at</strong>ion, Ministry of Agriculture,<br />

Government of India) <strong>for</strong> the years 1980·81 to 1992·93c For the remaining years,<br />

the same d<strong>at</strong>a have been collected from Fertiliser St<strong>at</strong>istics (the Fertiliser<br />

cc\ssoCI<strong>at</strong>ion of India, New Delhi), <strong>and</strong> St<strong>at</strong>istical Abstract {Director of Economics<br />

iHld St<strong>at</strong>istics, Ministry of Agriculture)c<br />

97


has been specified as an important variable th<strong>at</strong> determines the<br />

supply of credit. This variable is expected to be positively<br />

associ<strong>at</strong>ed with credit per hectare of gross cropped area.<br />

(b) Percentage of Area under Commercial Crops to Gross Cropped Area<br />

(CCP)<br />

Higher the area under commercial crops34, higher will be the<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> funds to meet the cost of production. Besides, the<br />

bankers may assume th<strong>at</strong> the commercial crop growers are safe<br />

borrowers in terms of repayment. Thus, an increase in the<br />

proportion of area under commercial crops to gross cropped area<br />

may positively influence the supply of agricultural credit.<br />

(e) Credit Deposit R<strong>at</strong>io (CDR)<br />

Deposit is one of the important sources of loanable funds. The<br />

volume of credit is assumed to be positively rel<strong>at</strong>ed with the level of<br />

deposits. The increase in the volume of deposits can enhance the<br />

volume of agricultural credit provided th<strong>at</strong> bankers perceive<br />

lending to <strong>agriculture</strong> as profitable. However, the CDR can increase<br />

due to either more flow of agricultural credit or non-agricultural<br />

credit or both. Hence, even if CDR Increases, this may not<br />

necessarily increase the supply of agricultural credit. Thus,<br />

increasing credit deposit r<strong>at</strong>io mayor may not lead to more supply<br />

of agricultural credit.<br />

34 It includes area under oilseeds (viz., groundnut, seasamum, rapeseed <strong>and</strong><br />

mustard oil, linseed, castorseed, nigerseed, safflower, sun-flower <strong>and</strong> soyabeen).<br />

cotton. Jute <strong>and</strong> mesta. tea, coffee. tobacco <strong>and</strong> sugarcane. These d<strong>at</strong>a have been<br />

collected from Indian Agricultural St<strong>at</strong>istics (1980-81 to 1992-93). <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> the<br />

rest of the years from St<strong>at</strong>istical Abstract.<br />

98


(d) Density of Bank Branches per 1,000 Farmers (DBB)<br />

It is explained in the liter<strong>at</strong>ure th<strong>at</strong> the problem of mounting<br />

overdues, poor quality of lending <strong>and</strong> recalcitrant <strong>at</strong>titude of the<br />

borrowers contributed to the cumul<strong>at</strong>ive losses to <strong>for</strong>mal financial<br />

institutions during the pre-re<strong>for</strong>m years 35 . This adversely affected<br />

the viability <strong>and</strong> efficiency of the rural banking system. There<strong>for</strong>e,<br />

during the re<strong>for</strong>m years <strong>and</strong> especially after the financial year<br />

1993-94, the loss making bank branches were directed to close<br />

down or merge them with their sponsored bank branches. The d<strong>at</strong>a<br />

show th<strong>at</strong> only the rural bank branches have been so far closed<br />

down. Thus, with the increasing popUl<strong>at</strong>ion size, the access to<br />

banking facility by rural popul<strong>at</strong>ion might have come down. Hence,<br />

it is important to see the rel<strong>at</strong>ionship between banking facility <strong>and</strong><br />

provisioning of agricultural credit.<br />

Since we are trying to measure vari<strong>at</strong>ion in credit per hectare of<br />

gross cropped area across the st<strong>at</strong>es, we have taken into account the<br />

density of bank branches per thous<strong>and</strong> farmers. As per the l<strong>at</strong>est<br />

agricultural census, the number of farmers <strong>for</strong> each st<strong>at</strong>e is available<br />

only <strong>for</strong> the years 1980-81, 1985-86, <strong>and</strong> 1990-91. So, we have<br />

calcul<strong>at</strong>ed the number of farmers <strong>for</strong> the rest of the years by<br />

extrapol<strong>at</strong>ion method (see, footnote 5) by using 1980-81 <strong>and</strong> 1990-91<br />

figures, <strong>and</strong> calcul<strong>at</strong>ed the density of bank branches <strong>for</strong> thous<strong>and</strong><br />

farmers in each st<strong>at</strong>e.<br />

li For more detailed discussion on these issues, see Von Pischke, Adams <strong>and</strong><br />

Donald 1983; Bravennan <strong>and</strong> Guasch 1989; Khusro 1989; Rajasekhar <strong>and</strong><br />

Ylasulu 1990, Vyasulu <strong>and</strong> Rajasekhar 1991; Kah10n 1991.<br />

99


Model Specific<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

Thus, in the model, the dependent variable "credit per hectare of gross<br />

cropped area" (CGA) is a function of the explan<strong>at</strong>ory variables of AIR,<br />

CCP, DBB <strong>and</strong> CDR. Since different st<strong>at</strong>es have different<br />

characteristics, we have used panel regression method to assess the<br />

individual impact of explan<strong>at</strong>ory variables. Another reason <strong>for</strong> using<br />

the panel regression method has been to get gre<strong>at</strong>er flexibility in<br />

modelling differences in behaviour across individual st<strong>at</strong>es. The<br />

individual effect is assumed to be constant over time <strong>and</strong> specific to<br />

the individual st<strong>at</strong>es.<br />

Hence, differences across the st<strong>at</strong>es can be<br />

captured in differences in constant term 36 .<br />

In order to specify a<br />

Functional <strong>for</strong>m, two altern<strong>at</strong>ive functional <strong>for</strong>ms, viz., linear <strong>and</strong> loglinear<br />

models _have been compared <strong>for</strong> the pooled d<strong>at</strong>a.. Sargan's<br />

criterion has been used to choose between the linear <strong>and</strong> log-linear<br />

specific<strong>at</strong>ion. The Sargan's criteria is computed as:<br />

Where,<br />

g ~t<strong>and</strong>s <strong>for</strong> the geometric mean of the dependent variable of the linear<br />

model.<br />

,i\l st<strong>and</strong>s <strong>for</strong> the Residual sum of square of the linear model.<br />

\ is the Residual sum of square of the log-linear model, <strong>and</strong><br />

T represents the number of observ<strong>at</strong>ions.<br />

The result of Sargan's criterion is given below in Table 4.6.<br />

It IS possible to allow the slopes to vary across the st<strong>at</strong>es. However, it reqUIres<br />

considerable complexity in the calcul<strong>at</strong>ion.<br />

100


Table 4.6: Estim<strong>at</strong>ion Result of Sargan's Criterion<br />

g Ou<br />

°v<br />

T 5<br />

916. 18 404491026.8 O. 132415 280 (3331471)280<br />

According to Sargan's criterion, if '5' is less than one, the linear<br />

model is preferred <strong>and</strong> if it is gre<strong>at</strong>er than one, then the log-linear<br />

model is preferred. Since our estim<strong>at</strong>ion result shows th<strong>at</strong> '5' is<br />

gre<strong>at</strong>er than one, it indic<strong>at</strong>es log-linear as the correct functional <strong>for</strong>m.<br />

The basic framework <strong>for</strong> using the pooled regression model can<br />

be specified as<br />

Yit = ~ + /3' Kit + E it<br />

There are k regressors in XiI excluding the constant term. The<br />

individual effect, ai which is taken to be constant over time t <strong>and</strong><br />

specific to the individual cross-section unit i. As it st<strong>and</strong>s, this model<br />

is a classical regression model. If we take ai to be the same across all<br />

units, then ordinary least squares provides consistent <strong>and</strong> efficient<br />

estim<strong>at</strong>es of a <strong>and</strong> p. There are two basic frameworks used to<br />

generalise this model. The Fixed Effect approach <strong>and</strong> R<strong>and</strong>om Effect<br />

takes a, to be a group specific constant <strong>and</strong> group-specific disturbance<br />

term in the regression model, respectively. With this background, we<br />

have used Fixed <strong>and</strong>/ R<strong>and</strong>om Effect model to estim<strong>at</strong>e the pooled<br />

regression parameters. The estim<strong>at</strong>ed equ<strong>at</strong>ion is as follows:<br />

log (GCA);t '" aj + 131 log (AIR);! + 132 log (CCP);! + 133 log (DBB);! + 134 log<br />

(CDR);! + E it<br />

Based on the least square residuals, we obtain a Lagrange<br />

iVlultiplier (LM) Test st<strong>at</strong>istic of 495.54 which far exceeds the 95 per<br />

cent critical value <strong>for</strong> chi-square with one degree of freedom (3.84). At<br />

101


this point, we conclude th<strong>at</strong> the classical regression model with single<br />

constant term is inappropri<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> these d<strong>at</strong>a. Furthermore, the result<br />

of the LM test is to reject the null hypothesis in favour of the R<strong>and</strong>om<br />

Effect Model. But it is best to reserve judgement on th<strong>at</strong> because there<br />

is another competing specific<strong>at</strong>ion th<strong>at</strong> might induce these same<br />

results, the Fixed Effect model. Keeping the fundamental difference in<br />

the two approaches in mind, we have calcul<strong>at</strong>ed Hausman Test <strong>for</strong> the<br />

Fixed <strong>and</strong> R<strong>and</strong>om Effect regression. This is based on the parts of the<br />

coefficient vectors <strong>and</strong> the asymptotic covariance m<strong>at</strong>rices th<strong>at</strong><br />

correspond to the slopes in the model, th<strong>at</strong> is, ignoring the constant<br />

term (s). The test st<strong>at</strong>istics is 73.09. The critical value from the chisquare<br />

table value with four degrees of freedom is 9.48, which is less<br />

than the test value. The hypothesis t.~<strong>at</strong> the individual effects are<br />

uncorrel<strong>at</strong>ed with the other regressors in the model can be rejected.<br />

Hence, we would conclude th<strong>at</strong> of the two altern<strong>at</strong>ives we have<br />

considered the Fixed Effect Model as the better choice <strong>for</strong> the<br />

interpret<strong>at</strong>ion, which is shown in the Table 4.7.<br />

Table 4.7: DescriptioD, Expected Sign, aDd CoefficieDt of<br />

Variables iD the Log-Linear Model [Dependent Variable = eGA]<br />

Variables Expected Filled Effect Model R<strong>and</strong>om Effect Model<br />

Sign Coefficient t· value Coefficient t - value<br />

Constant - - 2.38 ' 2.12<br />

~ AIR + 2.85' 11.79 1.98 ' 10.36<br />

I CCP + 0.26 1.29 0.64 ' 4.01<br />

DBB + 1. 43' 6.98 1.22 ' 6.49<br />

I CDR + - - 0.71 ' - 4.13 - 0.87 ' - 5.25<br />

. Lagrange Multiplier Test = 495.54<br />

Fixed vs. R<strong>and</strong>om Effects (Hausman) a 73.09<br />

, No of observ<strong>at</strong>ions E 280<br />

:-Iote: • <strong>at</strong> I % level of Significance


103<br />

Findings <strong>and</strong> Discussion<br />

The determinants of supply of credit per hectare of gross cropped area<br />

(eGA) are estim<strong>at</strong>ed by Fixed Effect Model (Table 4.7). Since it is a loglog<br />

model, the coefficients can be interpreted as elasticity. In our fIxed<br />

effect model, the explan<strong>at</strong>ory variables such as area under irrig<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

as a percentage of gross cropped area (AIR) <strong>and</strong> bank branches per<br />

thous<strong>and</strong> farmers (DBB) have got positive sign as expected. Moreover,<br />

both of them are signifIcant <strong>at</strong> 1 per cent level. The positive <strong>and</strong><br />

st<strong>at</strong>istically significant coefficient of AIR indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> 1 per cent<br />

increase in the irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area as a percentage of gross cropped area<br />

will lead to 2.85 per cent increase in the credit obtained per hectare of<br />

gross cropped area. This suggests th<strong>at</strong>, in any st<strong>at</strong>e, larger percentage<br />

of gross area irrig<strong>at</strong>ed to gross cropped area leads to a gre<strong>at</strong>er flow of<br />

agricultural credit by <strong>for</strong>mal fmancial institutions. Since irrig<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

facility reduces uncertainty of crops, bankers are probably giving<br />

priority to lend more in the irrig<strong>at</strong>ed belt. The positive <strong>and</strong> significant<br />

coefficient of DBB implies th<strong>at</strong> 1 per cent increase in the bank branch<br />

per thous<strong>and</strong> farmers will lead to 1.42 per cent increase in the credit<br />

per hectare of gross cropped area. Thus, given the policy of directed<br />

credit system, the st<strong>at</strong>es with higher DBB may be in a better position<br />

in terms of providing qualit<strong>at</strong>ive credit to the agricultural borrowers.<br />

During the re<strong>for</strong>m years the loss making bank branches were directed<br />

to close down or asked to merge with the sponsored banks. This<br />

happened only in the rural areas. As a consequence, the DBB might<br />

have come down, which, in tum, leading to reduced supply of<br />

agricultural credit.<br />

Though the variable CCP has an expected positive sign, it is not<br />

significant. The coefficient <strong>for</strong> the credit deposit r<strong>at</strong>io is neg<strong>at</strong>ive <strong>and</strong>


significant which means 1 per cent increase in the CDR leads to 0.71<br />

per cent decrease in the credit per hectare of gross cropped area. The<br />

neg<strong>at</strong>ive sign of CDR can be <strong>at</strong>tributed to perception among bankers<br />

th<strong>at</strong> loans to <strong>agriculture</strong> characterise high-risk. This suggests th<strong>at</strong><br />

even if we increase the CDR it may enhance the supply of credit<br />

outside the <strong>agriculture</strong> sector, which is considered by bankers to be a<br />

sector with better returns. Hence, as long as the bankers do not<br />

perceive lending to <strong>agriculture</strong> as profitable, increasing CDR itself is<br />

not enough <strong>for</strong> better provisioning of agricultural credit. On the whole,<br />

the farmers in the irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area or/<strong>and</strong> with high density of bank<br />

branches are most likely to benefit from institutional lending agencies.<br />

The intercepts of fixed effect model. <strong>for</strong> 14 st<strong>at</strong>es are glven In<br />

Table 4.8. This difference in intercepts can be <strong>at</strong>tributed to the unique<br />

fe<strong>at</strong>ures of each st<strong>at</strong>e. Although the evidence supports th<strong>at</strong> the Fixed<br />

Effect estim<strong>at</strong>es are generally held to be downward biased estim<strong>at</strong>es of<br />

the true effects, they are an improvement over cross-section d<strong>at</strong>a<br />

estim<strong>at</strong>es (Johnston <strong>and</strong> Oi Nardo 1997).<br />

Table 4.8: St<strong>at</strong>e Specific Intercepts of Fixed Effect Model<br />

! St<strong>at</strong>es Coefficient t - values<br />

IGular<strong>at</strong> - 0.78 - 0.66<br />

!Har\'ana - 2. 52 ••• - 1. 86<br />

~<br />

,Maharashtra 2. 16 ••• 1. 88<br />

,Punlab - 4. 41' - 3.40<br />

,Andhra Pradesh O. 20 0.15<br />

·Ka rna taka 1. 23 1. 03<br />

Kerala 3.58 • 3. 33<br />

\:ramil Nadu 0.03 0.02<br />

Illest Bengal 0.02 O. 02<br />

'R1har - 0.33 - 0.27<br />

·\l"dhya Pradesh 1. 01 O. 88<br />

.Onssa 0.47 O. 39<br />

PaJasthan - 0.23 - 0.20<br />

L' [tar Pradesh - 1. 70 - 1. 32<br />

. ,<br />

~Ole,<br />

<strong>at</strong> I % level of slgmficance, ••• <strong>at</strong> 10 % level of slgmficance<br />

104


credit Flow to Agriculture in Orissa<br />

The credit disbursed to agricultural sector in Orissa by SCBs<br />

(including RRBs) was Rs. 10,541.9 lakhs in 1991 <strong>and</strong> it had increased<br />

to Rs. 29,244.0 lakhs by 2000 <strong>at</strong> an annual growth r<strong>at</strong>e of 14.11 per<br />

cent. It is to be noted th<strong>at</strong> the share of agricultural credit from total<br />

bank credit has progressively declined from 55.5 per cent to 36.1 per<br />

cent during the same reference period (Table 4.9). Interestingly, this<br />

has been uni<strong>for</strong>m across CBs <strong>and</strong> RRBs. The r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>at</strong> which CBs<br />

disbursed credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> was about 54 per cent in 1991 <strong>and</strong> it<br />

increased to 59.8 per cent by the triennium ending with 1994. After<br />

this period, the r<strong>at</strong>e of credit disbursement to this sector gradually<br />

declined <strong>and</strong> reached to 36.5 per cent by the triennium ending with<br />

2000. In the case of RRBs, the disbursement r<strong>at</strong>e declined from 64.7<br />

per cent in 1991 to 35.4 per cent by 2000.<br />

Table 4.9: Share of Agricultural Credit (%) from Total Bank<br />

Cre d' It b )y E ac h G roup 0 fB an k<br />

Triennium Ending Commercial Regional Rural Total<br />

,,<br />

With Banks Banks<br />

1991' 54.0 64.7 55.5<br />

,<br />

1994 59.8 55.3 58.8<br />

I<br />

1997 50.2 41.8 47.6<br />

I 2000 36.5 35.4 36.1<br />

:-l<strong>at</strong>e: 1) * One year figure<br />

2) The figures are from disbursement loan amount.<br />

Source: UCO Bank (various issues of St<strong>at</strong>e Level Bankers' Committee Agenda Notes,<br />

Orissa starting from the year 1991 to 2000).<br />

The above raises the following issues. Why is th<strong>at</strong> the proportion<br />

of credit provided by both CBs <strong>and</strong> RRBs has been declining? Some of<br />

the bankers (<strong>at</strong> the ground level) are of the view th<strong>at</strong> since the retum<br />

on agricultural investment is highly uncertain <strong>and</strong> is affected by several<br />

jactors, <strong>and</strong> the probability of default r<strong>at</strong>e is more, banks are reluctant<br />

to extend their credit facility to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector. It is also argued th<strong>at</strong><br />

the failure of the commercial banks in extending credit facility to the<br />

\05


ural poor <strong>and</strong> especially to the farmers was <strong>at</strong>tributed mainly to their<br />

policy of coll<strong>at</strong>eral-based lending 37 (Shylendra 1996). The annual<br />

reports of one of the RRBs in the st<strong>at</strong>e note th<strong>at</strong> the bank has been<br />

trying to lend more of its funds to non-agricultural purposes<br />

particularly to those th<strong>at</strong> come under the non-priority c<strong>at</strong>egories. This<br />

was done mainly because the non-agricultural loans not only had<br />

better chances of recovery but also fetched rel<strong>at</strong>ively higher interest<br />

r<strong>at</strong>es. Elsewhere, it has been argued th<strong>at</strong> the increasing oper<strong>at</strong>ing<br />

costs <strong>and</strong> higher loans delinquency r<strong>at</strong>es compelled the bank to adopt<br />

such a str<strong>at</strong>egy (Shylendra 1995). The less supply of agricultural<br />

credit by RRB as a proportion to its total bank credit can also be<br />

<strong>at</strong>tributed to the policy of allowing the RRB to lend up to 60 per cent<br />

of their incremental lending to non-target groups (RB! 1995).<br />

From the disbursement figure one can suggest th<strong>at</strong> there is<br />

growing preference of lending to non-agricultural sector by both<br />

commercial <strong>and</strong> regional rural banks. This preference <strong>for</strong> nonagricultural<br />

loans can also be corrobor<strong>at</strong>ed by the d<strong>at</strong>a on targets <strong>and</strong><br />

achievement with respect to different sectors within the priority<br />

sectors lending. Sector-wise distribution of target <strong>and</strong> achievement of<br />

all scheduled commercial banks in Orissa in priority sectors under<br />

various annual credit plan during the period 1991-92 to 1999-2000<br />

has been presented in Table 4.10.<br />

Table 4.10 shows th<strong>at</strong> within the priority sectors lending more<br />

than 50 per cent of the targeted loan amounts were going to<br />

37 Von Pischke, Adams <strong>and</strong> Donald (1983) <strong>and</strong> others argue th<strong>at</strong> such a policy is the<br />

result of cheap interest r<strong>at</strong>es prescribed on farm loans. In order to sustain themselves<br />

financially the lenders adopt the credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning process by pursuing<br />

coll<strong>at</strong>eral based lending, which ultim<strong>at</strong>ely leads to the elimin<strong>at</strong>ion of small<br />

borrowers.<br />

106


<strong>agriculture</strong> sector up to the year 1994. After th<strong>at</strong>, the targeted loan<br />

amounts to this sector had progressively declined from 58.1 per cent<br />

to 44.2 per cent by the triennium ending with 2000. This can be<br />

<strong>at</strong>tributed to the declined trend of proportion<strong>at</strong>ely targeted loan<br />

amounts <strong>for</strong> crop loans <strong>and</strong> allied agricultural activities. Against the<br />

total target of priority sector lending, the proportions of achievement<br />

in the supply of all kinds of agricultural credit lies always well below<br />

the target. Furthennore, this achievement r<strong>at</strong>e under <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

sector has been declining since mid nineties. There<strong>for</strong>e, as far as<br />

agricultural credit flow is concerned, the perfonnance of scheduled<br />

commercial banks can be summarised as lower achievement of lower<br />

targets.<br />

Table 4.10: Broad Secto~se Distribution ~f Target <strong>and</strong><br />

Achievements under Annual Credit Plan of SCBs (includin~<br />

RRB)<br />

TrienniuJIl Crop A&rlcultural AIlled to ToW Small Services ToW<br />

Ending Lou Term Lou A&rlcalture Apiculture Scs1e<br />

With (ATlAl Industries<br />

Distribution of Targets %)<br />

1991 21.7 16.5 13.3 51.5 21.9 26.5 100<br />

r<br />

(23,960.72)<br />

1994 24.8 19.2 14.1 58.1 17.2 24.7 100<br />

I<br />

(23,747.46)<br />

1997 19.2 18.5 11.4 49.1 19.4 31.5 100<br />

1(43,807.10)<br />

2000 17.4 19.3 7.5 44.2 17.5 38.3 100<br />

I (76 906.58)<br />

Distribution of Achievement to Total Targets %}<br />

1991 17.9 16.3 9.8 44.0 6.6 28.7 79.3<br />

I 1994 22.3 15.9 8.9 47.0 12.1 20.8 79.9<br />

1997 22.1 14.1 10.9 47.1 13.6 38.2 98.9<br />

,<br />

2000 18.5 9.6 7.0 35.1 12.8 49.3 97.2<br />

Note: 11 Figures m parenthesIs represent total target amount (Rs. m Lakhsl <strong>for</strong> the<br />

above mentioned sectors in the Orissa st<strong>at</strong>e.<br />

21 • One year figure<br />

Source: veo Bank (various issues of St<strong>at</strong>e Level Bankers' Committee Agenda Notes,<br />

Orissa starting from the year 1991 to 2000).<br />

It is, however, clear th<strong>at</strong> banks show preference to lend to<br />

services in comparison to other sectors within the priority lending. The<br />

distribution of target <strong>and</strong> the r<strong>at</strong>e of achievement to this sector show<br />

107


108<br />

th<strong>at</strong> both have been increasing over a period of time. The proportion of<br />

targeted loan amounts <strong>for</strong> the service sector range from 24.7 per cent<br />

to 38.3 per cent, whereas, the achievement to total target vary from<br />

28.7 to 49.3 per cent. This shows th<strong>at</strong> the r<strong>at</strong>e of achievement is<br />

always more than the r<strong>at</strong>e of target in the case of service sector.<br />

Hence, the credit flow to service sector can be termed as higher<br />

achievement of lower targets. On the whole, the higher r<strong>at</strong>e of<br />

achievement by scheduled commercial banks (including RRB) m<br />

priority sectors lending (<strong>for</strong> instance, 99 per cent <strong>and</strong> 97 per cent in<br />

triennium ending with 1997 <strong>and</strong> 2000 respectively) can be <strong>at</strong>tributed<br />

to a higher r<strong>at</strong>e of achievement in service sector.<br />

The <strong>for</strong>egoing discussion suggests th<strong>at</strong> there is a decline in the<br />

proportion of credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector from the total credit<br />

disbursed. The dem<strong>and</strong> side factors have been emphasised <strong>for</strong> such a<br />

poor achievement in the supply of agricultural credit (Government of<br />

Orissa 2000-01). First, the number of proposals coming from farmers<br />

especially in the case of ATLs has been inadequ<strong>at</strong>e. Second, poor<br />

recovery of bank loans. Third, the infrastructure in rural areas is not<br />

adequ<strong>at</strong>ely developed. Fourth, the credit absorption capacity among<br />

the farmers in rural areas is very low. Fifth, banks do not have<br />

adequ<strong>at</strong>e manpower to meet the growing credit needs of the farmers. It<br />

is also argued th<strong>at</strong> the lower achievement in the case of ATLs can be<br />

<strong>at</strong>tributed to the policy decision th<strong>at</strong> no direct coll<strong>at</strong>eral security is<br />

needed <strong>for</strong> loans up to Rs. 50,000. This suggests th<strong>at</strong> the bankers<br />

seem to be adopting non-price credit mechanisms in the case of ATLs.<br />

Poor extension support, low irrig<strong>at</strong>ion coverage, untimely <strong>and</strong><br />

inadequ<strong>at</strong>e supply of inputs, <strong>and</strong> low level of fertiliser consumption


were identified as important constraints <strong>for</strong> a declining r<strong>at</strong>e of<br />

achievement in the case of production credit (NABARD 2001-02).<br />

In the case of small-scale industries also a similar kind of<br />

situ<strong>at</strong>ion can be observed like <strong>agriculture</strong>. The r<strong>at</strong>e of achievement is<br />

very poor compared to the given target <strong>for</strong> this sector. Factors like lack<br />

of adequ<strong>at</strong>e facilities <strong>for</strong> skill upgrad<strong>at</strong>ion, inadequ<strong>at</strong>e infrastructure<br />

facilities, lack of road communic<strong>at</strong>ion to rural areas, no marketing<br />

outlets <strong>for</strong> h<strong>and</strong>icrafts items, low level of people's awareness, no<br />

proper industrial survey, <strong>and</strong> absence of <strong>for</strong>ward <strong>and</strong> backward<br />

linkages were some of the important constraints <strong>at</strong>tributed to such a<br />

poor achievement in the supply of credit to the small-scale industrial<br />

sector (NABARD 2001-02).<br />

This suggests th<strong>at</strong> bankers, by <strong>and</strong> large, exclude supply side<br />

factors from their purview. Can the decline in the credit flow to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> be <strong>at</strong>tributed to profitability consider<strong>at</strong>ion getting reflected<br />

in the <strong>for</strong>m of price <strong>and</strong> non-price types of credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning in the<br />

situ<strong>at</strong>ion of interest r<strong>at</strong>e controls (in the case of commercial banks)<br />

<strong>and</strong> inability to have direct coll<strong>at</strong>eral security in the case of certain<br />

loans? If this is the case, there is a possibility of having a situ<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

where dem<strong>and</strong> exceeds the supply of agricultural credit. This raises<br />

another set of issues. In the case of which type of farmers <strong>and</strong><br />

activities, the credit is r<strong>at</strong>ioned? Is credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning leading to a<br />

situ<strong>at</strong>ion where this is confined to a particular type of borrowers?<br />

However, these questions have been addressed in the subsequent<br />

chapters.<br />

109


110<br />

District Level <strong>Analysis</strong> on Agricultural Credit Flow<br />

Prior to 1993, there were 13 districts in the st<strong>at</strong>e Orissa. In 1994, 17<br />

more districts were cre<strong>at</strong>ed from out of 10 districts. Thus, the total<br />

number of districts became 30. The bifurc<strong>at</strong>ion was done in such a<br />

manner th<strong>at</strong> one or more new districts were carved out of one of the<br />

older districts. Thus, it is possible <strong>for</strong> one to rework the d<strong>at</strong>a <strong>for</strong><br />

undivided districts. The same has been done in this study as well.<br />

There<strong>for</strong>e, the in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion presented in this study rel<strong>at</strong>es to the 13<br />

undivided districts.<br />

There is considerable vari<strong>at</strong>ion across these districts in the<br />

<strong>levels</strong> of irrig<strong>at</strong>ion infrastructure, fertiliser consumption <strong>and</strong> area<br />

under HYVs. All these will have significant influence on the flow of<br />

credit to <strong>agriculture</strong>. After analysing the d<strong>at</strong>a on these variables <strong>for</strong><br />

each of the undivided districts, we have c<strong>at</strong>egorised the districts into<br />

three groups, viz., advanced, intermediary <strong>and</strong> backward districts. The<br />

dIstricts of Cuttack, Puri, Sambalpur <strong>and</strong> Ganjam come under the<br />

advanced group, while Baleswar, Bolangir, Dhenkanal <strong>and</strong> Koraput<br />

<strong>for</strong>m the intermediary group. Finally, the districts of Kalah<strong>and</strong>i,<br />

Keonjhar, Mayurbhanj, Phulbani <strong>and</strong> Sundargarh <strong>for</strong>m the backward<br />

group. Table 4.11 shows th<strong>at</strong> such a grouping is justified.<br />

The increased concentr<strong>at</strong>ion of development can be seen from<br />

the distribution of agricultural credit in Table 4.12. The advanced<br />

districts take a share, on an average, 58.68 per cent of the total<br />

outst<strong>and</strong>ing loans disbursed to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector during the period<br />

1981-85. This share ranges from 54.12 per cent to 60.05 per cent of<br />

total outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit <strong>for</strong> the remaining period mentioned in the<br />

table. For intermediary districts, the share of agricultural credit, on an<br />

average, vary within the range of 24.16 per cent to 26.38 per cent,


\\'hereas, these shares vary in between 14.95 per cent <strong>and</strong> 19.50 per<br />

cent <strong>for</strong> backward districts during the last two decades. Seen in terms<br />

of distribution of agricultural credit one can notice th<strong>at</strong> the advanced<br />

group of districts takes a lion share compared to intermediary <strong>and</strong><br />

backward districts. In this context, one can conclude th<strong>at</strong> the flow of<br />

credit to different regions is far from uni<strong>for</strong>m.<br />

Table 4.11: Some Selected Indic<strong>at</strong>ors of Sp<strong>at</strong>ial Distribution of<br />

Development<br />

Type of Districts<br />

% Share Irri,-<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

1987- 88 1994 - 95 1999 - 2000<br />

: Ad\'anced 58.4 54.0 51.4<br />

i;'termediarv 26.7 30.3 30.9<br />

'-S'ackward 14.9 15.7 17.7<br />

, All' 100 100 100<br />

(2,062.831 (2,468.33) (2,512.02)<br />

% Share of Area under High Yieldin Variety seeds<br />

,\d.'.'unced 49.4 48.4


Wh<strong>at</strong> are the trends in the share of agricultural credit from net<br />

bank credit of SCBs <strong>for</strong> all the districts? Table 4.13 shows th<strong>at</strong><br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> accounted <strong>for</strong> 19 per cent of the net bank credit <strong>for</strong> the<br />

period 1996-2000 <strong>for</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e of Orissa as a whole <strong>and</strong> meeting the<br />

target fIxed under the priority sector lending. However, this share was,<br />

on an average, 31.3 per cent during the period 1981-85, <strong>and</strong> it<br />

declined to 20.7 per cent during 1991-95. This suggests th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

supply of agricultural credit as a proportion to net bank credit have<br />

been declining in the st<strong>at</strong>e of Orissa. This was uni<strong>for</strong>m across the<br />

districts. Nevertheless, the proportion of agricultural credit from net<br />

bank credit have been declining, still, the bank has achieved the fIxed<br />

target <strong>for</strong> all the intermediary <strong>and</strong> backward districts except<br />

Sundargarh, <strong>and</strong> also has achieved th.e target <strong>for</strong> Ganjam <strong>and</strong><br />

Sambalpur among the advanced districts. In the case of Sundargarh<br />

district, the achievement r<strong>at</strong>e of agricultural credit was far below the<br />

prescribed r<strong>at</strong>e during both pre <strong>and</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m years.<br />

During the period, 1981 to 2000, ACBD declined progressively<br />

<strong>for</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e Orissa as a whole from 23.7 per cent <strong>for</strong> the years 1981-<br />

85 to 9 per cent during 1996-2000 (Table 4.13). However, the declined<br />

ACBD during 1980s <strong>for</strong> Orissa could be mainly <strong>at</strong>tributed to the<br />

declined trend of ACBD among the intermediary districts. This r<strong>at</strong>io<br />

declined uni<strong>for</strong>mly <strong>for</strong> the entire district in the st<strong>at</strong>e during 1990s.<br />

Table 4.13 shows th<strong>at</strong> there were substantial inter-district differences<br />

in ACBD both <strong>at</strong> one period of time as well as between four time<br />

periods. Importantly, <strong>for</strong> the backward districts like Sundargarh, only<br />

3.4 per cent of net bank deposit was going to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector as<br />

credit. Even in the advanced districts like Cuttack, Gunjam <strong>and</strong> Puri<br />

also, the ACBD varied between 6 to 8 per cent during 1996-2000.<br />

I I")


Since both ACBC <strong>and</strong> ACBD have been declining <strong>for</strong> all the districts<br />

during 1990s, this again confirms the result of all India <strong>and</strong> st<strong>at</strong>e level<br />

imalysis th<strong>at</strong> bankers were giving priority to non-agricultural lending.<br />

Table 4.13: District-wise Agricultural Sector Lending (%) to<br />

T otal Ban k C re d't 1 an d D eposlts .<br />

Districts<br />

c '\lttack<br />

.imjam<br />

p ;1;1<br />

S ambalpur<br />

G roup Total<br />

)aleswar<br />

B ()Iangir<br />

[ lhenkanal<br />

h ·uraput<br />

G roup Total<br />

·alah<strong>and</strong>i<br />

·ecmjhar<br />

!.'.'urbhanj<br />

lhulbani<br />

~t~lldargarh<br />

G . roup Total<br />

1981·85 1986·90<br />

ACBC ACBD ACBC ACBO<br />

29.1 24.1 20.0 20.4<br />

35.8 18.2 39.1 28.4<br />

29.0 20.6 19.0 18.9<br />

28.9 21.7 32.8 30.8<br />

29.8 21.5 23.4 22.3<br />

36.6 27.4 30.8 28.7<br />

53.2 97.4 44.1 75.4<br />

34.2 20.2 27.9 21.6<br />

41.3 49.1 35.8 41.6<br />

42.2 41.8 34.4 36.1<br />

46.1 67.2 41.9 65.4<br />

19.1 22.1 21.9 22.4<br />

31.6 29.7 25.7 24.9<br />

60.8 63.4 43.7 38.3<br />

9.3 5.1 12.7 7.9<br />

24.8 19.4 23.5 19.6<br />

31.3 23.7 25.3 23.2<br />

1991·95 1996-2~~<br />

ACBC ACBO ACBC ACBO<br />

16.8 11.4 [6.1 7.4<br />

29.6 15.4 22.8 7.9<br />

15.4 9.8 13.7 6.2<br />

22.1 14.9 21.5 12.7<br />

18.4 11.7 16.7 7.6<br />

24.8 22.2 20.5 13.8<br />

32.1 31.! 30.6 17.9<br />

27.4 14.6 26.2 10.2<br />

28.0 22.2 31.2 15.9<br />

27.4 20.9 25.8 13.7<br />

38.5 35.8 35.9 24.3<br />

25.5 18.2 19.5 10.1<br />

23.9 13.4 33.0 12.6<br />

35.3 24.2 32.4 18.6<br />

10.1 4.8 8.3 3.4<br />

21.2 12.3 20.7 9.6<br />

20.7 13.4 19.0 9.0<br />

A II Orissa<br />

\,lle: ACBC = Agncultural sector credIt as a proportIon to net bank credIt.<br />

ACBD = Agricultural sector credit as a proportion to total bank deposit.<br />

Source: RBI (various issues of Banking St<strong>at</strong>istics starting from the year 1981 to<br />

2000).<br />

As we have mentioned <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level analysis th<strong>at</strong>, if more<br />

(less) proportion of net bank credit is disbursed to the <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

sector th<strong>at</strong> does not necessarily mean th<strong>at</strong> the per capita credit<br />

availability per hectare of gross cropped area is more (less) in th<strong>at</strong><br />

st<strong>at</strong>e. Since this proportion does not take into account the gross<br />

cropped area, it may be difficult to reach a conclusion on the basis of<br />

proportion of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> to total net bank credit th<strong>at</strong> a<br />

particular st<strong>at</strong>e/district is better-off in terms of the availability of<br />

agricultural credit. The above proposition has been verified in Table<br />

-+14.<br />

J 13


Table 4.14. Type of District-wise Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Credit Per<br />

Hectare of Gross Cropped Area<br />

Jin Rupees)<br />

1<br />

Type of Average <strong>for</strong> the Average <strong>for</strong> the Average <strong>for</strong> the<br />

Districts Period 1986-90 Period 1991-95 Period 1996-00<br />

~ Advanced 683 771 1,249<br />

'Intermediary 342 423 747<br />

r Backward 263 338 671<br />

; All 458 537 925<br />

Source: Government of Orissa (various Issues of Onssa Agncu/tura/ St<strong>at</strong>zstzcs from<br />

1985-86 to 1999- 2000) <strong>and</strong> Reserve Bank of India (various issues of<br />

Banking St<strong>at</strong>istics from 1986 to 1999-2000).<br />

It can be seen from Table 4.14 th<strong>at</strong> the credit availability per<br />

hectare of gross cropped area varies across the regions <strong>and</strong> time<br />

periods. Importantly, the regions/districts where banks achieved their<br />

lending target to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector, the supply of credit per hectare of<br />

gross cropped area was less in most of those regions. For instance, in<br />

the advanced districts only 16.7 per cent of net bank credit was going<br />

to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector <strong>and</strong> credit per hectare of gross cropped area was<br />

Rs. 1,249 <strong>for</strong> the period 1996-2000 (Tables 4.13 <strong>and</strong> 4.14), whereas,<br />

in the case of intermediary <strong>and</strong> backward districts, the share of<br />

agricultural credit were 25.8 per cent <strong>and</strong> 20.7 per cent of net bank<br />

credit, <strong>and</strong> the credit available per hectare of gross cropped area were<br />

Rs. 747 <strong>and</strong> Rs. 671 respectively during the same reference period. It<br />

shows th<strong>at</strong> the per capita credit per hectare of gross cropped area in<br />

intermediary <strong>and</strong> backward districts were far below than the advanced<br />

districts. There<strong>for</strong>e, the <strong>for</strong>mal credit available per hectare of gross<br />

cropped area could be a better indic<strong>at</strong>or to examine the inter-districts<br />

vari<strong>at</strong>ions in the flow of agricultural credit.


Determinants of Supply of Agricultural Credit <strong>at</strong> the District<br />

Level<br />

To examine vari<strong>at</strong>ions in the availability of credit per hectare of gross<br />

lTopped area across the districts, we have used the same methodology<br />

th<strong>at</strong> we have adopted <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level analysis. With the same<br />

ckfinition, both dependent <strong>and</strong> independent variables were specified,<br />

<strong>and</strong> by using the same functional <strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong> the fixed effect <strong>and</strong> r<strong>and</strong>om<br />

effect models have been estim<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>at</strong> the district level analysis 36 .<br />

Since the Langrange Multiplier Test st<strong>at</strong>istics of 42.91, which<br />

exceeds the 95 per cent critical value of chi-square with one degree of<br />

freedom (3.84), we conclude th<strong>at</strong> the classical regression model with<br />

'nITI~ ~onstant term l'~ in:::lnnT"('\nri-::ltp fn.,. th.:llC'A ~.-d·"" ~"-"\...."""-mo-e ,1.._<br />

SI Eo \. \.. -' - - '- -- -rr- -1"" .... _ .... - .................... " .... UULQ • .1 U.l Ll1\"'.l 1 " , Lile:<br />

Hausman Test st<strong>at</strong>istics of Fixed versus R<strong>and</strong>om Effects is 7.45,<br />

\\'hich is less than the chi-square table value (9.48) with four degrees<br />

of freedom. Thus, the hypothesis th<strong>at</strong> the individual effects are<br />

uncorrel<strong>at</strong>ed with the other regressors in the model can be accepted.<br />

There<strong>for</strong>e, out of two altern<strong>at</strong>ives we considered R<strong>and</strong>om Effect Model<br />

is the better choice <strong>for</strong> the interpret<strong>at</strong>ion, which is shown in Table<br />

~.15. Although the evidence supports th<strong>at</strong> the R<strong>and</strong>om Effect<br />

estim<strong>at</strong>es are generally held to be upwards-biased estim<strong>at</strong>es of the<br />

true effects, they are an improvement over cross-section d<strong>at</strong>a<br />

estim<strong>at</strong>es (Johnston <strong>and</strong> Oi Nardo 1997) .<br />

. SlIlce the specific<strong>at</strong>ion of variables (both dependent <strong>and</strong> independent). functional<br />

<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong> <strong>and</strong> other details of methodology have been explained <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level<br />

analysis, the similar set of explan<strong>at</strong>ion has not been given to avoid repetition <strong>at</strong><br />

the district level analysis.<br />

115


Table 4.15: Description, Expected Sign, <strong>and</strong> Coefficient of<br />

Variables in the Log-Linear Model [Dependent variable = CGA]<br />

-<br />

" Variables Expected Fixed Effect Model R<strong>and</strong>om Effect Model<br />

,<br />

Sign Coefficient t - value Coefficient<br />

i<br />

t - value<br />

, Constant -<br />

- 8.37' lO.41<br />


sl'lyice by other line departments, lack of timely availability of<br />

ltTlg<strong>at</strong>ion facility, untimely <strong>and</strong> inadequ<strong>at</strong>e supply of inputs, <strong>and</strong> low<br />

i,'\-ei of fertiliser consumption can be <strong>at</strong>tributed to this neg<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

dssoci<strong>at</strong>ion (NABARD 2001-02), As a result of this, the bankers may<br />

ill' adopting non-price credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning mechanism <strong>for</strong> commercial crop<br />

gmwers, Though the variable DBB has an expected positive sign, it is<br />

not significant.<br />

The coefficient of CDR is neg<strong>at</strong>ive <strong>and</strong> significant <strong>at</strong> 1 per cent<br />

level. This suggests th<strong>at</strong> one per cent increase in the CDR reduces the<br />

supply of agricultural credit by 6.85 per cent. This finding also<br />

support the result of the st<strong>at</strong>e level analysis th<strong>at</strong> increasing CDR itself<br />

is not enough <strong>for</strong> better provisioning of agricultural credit. On the<br />

\\hole, the farmers in the higher irrig<strong>at</strong>ed regions are most likely<br />

beneficiaries of agricultural credit. The fixed effect intercepts of 13<br />

districts, which are presented in Table 4.16, one can argue th<strong>at</strong> this<br />

difference in intercepts can be <strong>at</strong>tributed to the unique fe<strong>at</strong>ures of<br />

each district.<br />

Conclusions<br />

This chapter analysed the trends in the supply of agricultural credit<br />

')\- II1stitutional agencies in 14 major st<strong>at</strong>es, <strong>and</strong> across the districts in<br />

(lrissa st<strong>at</strong>e. It is found th<strong>at</strong> the growth r<strong>at</strong>e of agricultural credit was<br />

'l:gher during pre-re<strong>for</strong>m period compared to the re<strong>for</strong>m period m<br />

rnost of the st<strong>at</strong>es. It is also observed th<strong>at</strong> the growth r<strong>at</strong>e of<br />

clgncultural credit was uneven during the sub-periods as well as<br />

",TOSS the st<strong>at</strong>es. There were also substantial inter-st<strong>at</strong>e differences in<br />

.\c:ncuitural Credit as a proportion to total net Bank Credit (ACBC)<br />

"!lei Agricultural Credit as a proportion to Bank Deposits (ACBD) <strong>at</strong><br />

117


one point in time as well as during different time periods. An analysis<br />

of the ACBD demonstr<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> since this has been declining <strong>for</strong> all<br />

the major st<strong>at</strong>es, it shows th<strong>at</strong> there was less mobilis<strong>at</strong>ion of deposits<br />

<strong>for</strong> agricultural lending by scheduled commercial banks. This was<br />

particularly the case in backward st<strong>at</strong>es like Bihar, Uttar Pradesh,<br />

<strong>and</strong> West Bengal.<br />

Most of the findings of the district level analysis were similar to<br />

th<strong>at</strong> of the st<strong>at</strong>e level analysis. Important similarities between the<br />

district <strong>and</strong> st<strong>at</strong>e level findings include the declining share of<br />

agricultural credit from net bank credit <strong>and</strong> uneven credit flow across<br />

the regions. The differences in the availability of credit per hectare of<br />

gross cropped area across the regions is another common finding in<br />

both st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> district level analysis. This suggests th<strong>at</strong> the flow of<br />

agricultural credit follows similar p<strong>at</strong>terns <strong>at</strong> both st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> district<br />

<strong>levels</strong>.<br />

With regard to the analysis of trends in credit flow in Orissa, it<br />

is found th<strong>at</strong> the r<strong>at</strong>e of credit disbursed to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector by SCBs<br />

was declining during 1990s. The analysis reveals th<strong>at</strong> as far as the<br />

disbursement of agricultural credit is concerned, the SCBs per<strong>for</strong>med<br />

poorly in so far as the achievement of targets is concerned. The views<br />

of bankers <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> district <strong>levels</strong> have been examined to<br />

underst<strong>and</strong> the reasons <strong>for</strong> the failure to achieve the targets on<br />

agricultural sector. The qualit<strong>at</strong>ive in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion (collected from bankers<br />

<strong>and</strong> NABARD reports) suggests th<strong>at</strong> the dem<strong>and</strong> side problems<br />

including poor recovery, inadequ<strong>at</strong>e infrastructure support <strong>and</strong> low<br />

credit absorption capacity of the agricultural borrowers are the main


,'onstraints In the supply of agricultural crediL This suggests th<strong>at</strong><br />

bankers, by <strong>and</strong> large, exclude supply side factors from their purview,<br />

The proportion of irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area to gross cropped area, <strong>and</strong><br />

density of bank branches per 1,000 farmers have been identified as<br />

the most important explan<strong>at</strong>ory variables <strong>for</strong> the vari<strong>at</strong>ions in the<br />

credit flow per hectare of gross cropped area. However, the neg<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

associ<strong>at</strong>ion between CDR <strong>and</strong> credit per hectare of gross cropped<br />

indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> an increase in CDR need not necessarily ensure<br />

improved credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong>. This will happen only when the<br />

bankers perceive the agricultural lending to be profitable, The factors<br />

like irrig<strong>at</strong>ion facility <strong>and</strong> CDR also behave in the similar way <strong>at</strong> the<br />

district levd analysis. Th~ implic<strong>at</strong>ion of this finding is th<strong>at</strong> <strong>for</strong> better<br />

provisioning of agricultural credit the increasing CDR should be<br />

backed by more irrig<strong>at</strong>ion facility <strong>and</strong> banking infrastructure.<br />

The analysis on access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit <strong>and</strong> the outst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

loan amount per account reveal th<strong>at</strong> there are inter-st<strong>at</strong>e differences<br />

in the access to credit as well as the loan amount obtained by farm<br />

households even <strong>for</strong> the same size class of l<strong>and</strong>holding, In this<br />

context, the following questions can be raised. First, wh<strong>at</strong> makes some<br />

farmers to access <strong>for</strong>mal credit, while others do not? Second, how do<br />

bankers fix up the credit limit <strong>for</strong> different c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers?<br />

These questions have been taken up in the sixth chapter.<br />

_-----'119


Chapter 5<br />

HOW DID MACRO POLICY OPERATE AT THE MICRO<br />

LEVEL? AN ANALYSIS OF CREDIT FLOW IN THE<br />

SELECTED BANK BRANCHES IN KALAHANDI DISTRICT,<br />

ORISSA<br />

Introduction<br />

The <strong>macro</strong>-level policies on agricultural <strong>finance</strong> have been primarily<br />

concerned with the level of credit flow, terms <strong>and</strong> conditions under<br />

which credit is made available, alloc<strong>at</strong>ion of loanable funds among<br />

sub-sectors (production <strong>and</strong> investment) within <strong>agriculture</strong> to achieve<br />

production efficiency <strong>and</strong> so on. The <strong>macro</strong> level policy also concerns<br />

with the provision of adequ<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> timely availability of credit to the<br />

needy farmers <strong>at</strong> a cheaper r<strong>at</strong>e. These policies, in general, give<br />

guidelines to the ground level institutional financing agencies having<br />

direct contact with the borrowers. Since institutional credit is a<br />

cheaper source <strong>for</strong> borrowing, most of the theoretical <strong>and</strong> empirical<br />

studies have put <strong>for</strong>ward the argument th<strong>at</strong> the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit far<br />

exceeds the supply (Kamajou 1980; Gonzalez-Vega 1984; Adams <strong>and</strong><br />

Vogel 1986; Kochar 1997; Swain 2002). There<strong>for</strong>e, many countries<br />

<strong>and</strong> financial institutions followed the supply-led approach to meet<br />

the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit. In the case of India, the supply-led approach in<br />

terms of directed lending was introduced to priority sectors, in<br />

general, <strong>and</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong>, in particular.<br />

As a consequence to the supply-led approach <strong>at</strong> cheaper r<strong>at</strong>e,<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal financial agencies began to face the problem of higher<br />

transaction costs on account of lending small amounts to large<br />

number of borrowers (McKinnon 1973; Shaw 1973; Anderson <strong>and</strong><br />

\\hamb<strong>at</strong>a 1985; Gadgi11986; S<strong>at</strong>ish <strong>and</strong> Swamin<strong>at</strong>h 1989; Desai <strong>and</strong>


121<br />

Namboodiri 1992). The disbursal of loans without asseSSIng the<br />

feasibility, viability of the project <strong>and</strong> entrepreneurial capacity of the<br />

borrowers leading to the problem of high overdues <strong>and</strong> the problem of<br />

recurring losses in the case of most of the rural <strong>for</strong>mal financial<br />

institutions were noticed in India during 1980s (Khusro 1989;<br />

Rajasekhar <strong>and</strong> Vyasulu 1990; Vyasulu <strong>and</strong> Rajasekhar 1991; Kahlon<br />

1991). This adversely affected the efficiency <strong>and</strong> viability of the rural<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal financial agencies.<br />

The Narasimham Committee (1991) recommended <strong>for</strong> a gradual<br />

reduction in the priority sector target from 40 to 10 per cent of the<br />

total bank credit. However, the RBI did not fully accept this<br />

recommend<strong>at</strong>ion on the grounds th<strong>at</strong> the redefined priority sectors<br />

certainly accounted <strong>for</strong> more than 10 per cent of the total credit.<br />

Further, the recommend<strong>at</strong>ion, if accepted, would put a severe squeeze<br />

on the sectors included in the priority lending. At the same time,<br />

various policy measures aimed <strong>at</strong> diluting the norms of priority sector<br />

lending were taken, so as to ensure its gradual phasing out in the<br />

long-run.<br />

On the whole, the str<strong>at</strong>egy followed by the RBI was to keep the<br />

same target in so far as priority sector was concerned <strong>and</strong> widened the<br />

,'overage of the priority sector, in general, <strong>and</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong>, In<br />

particular 39 . Since the coverage of the priority sector differed In<br />

different years in 1990s, it is necessary to analyse the share of these<br />

sectors in the total advance by public sector banks. Shajahan (1998)<br />

shows th<strong>at</strong> the share of priority sector lending had gone down after<br />

I he banking sector re<strong>for</strong>m. This declining share continued up to 1996-<br />

For more details on the widening coverage of <strong>agriculture</strong> sector, see 3.4 section of<br />

Chapter Ill. Also see, Shajahan (1998, 1999).


97. However, with the widening of the scope of priority sector by the<br />

RBI on a substantial scale during 1997-98 <strong>and</strong> 1998-99, the share of<br />

priority sector lending went up during these years <strong>and</strong> after (Shajahan<br />

1999). Thus, it appears th<strong>at</strong> banks alloc<strong>at</strong>ed more funds to the newly<br />

included sectors <strong>and</strong> activities in the priority sector to cover the<br />

shortfall in the priority sector lending. There<strong>for</strong>e, the extent to which<br />

the banks diverted advances from areas already in the priority sector<br />

to the newly included areas is an important aspect of priority sector<br />

lending, which needs to be analysed. In this chapter, an <strong>at</strong>tempt has<br />

been made to discuss the credit flow to the priority sector, in general,<br />

lI1d <strong>agriculture</strong>, in particular, with the help of d<strong>at</strong>a from four bank<br />

branches in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district. The objectives of the chapter are to:<br />

1. find out the share of<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>, in particular<br />

selected bank branches;<br />

• • • 1-1<br />

pnontj" sectors, in generaL, allY<br />

out of the total advances of the<br />

2. identify the activities (both <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> non-<strong>agriculture</strong><br />

which are coming under the priority sector) <strong>for</strong> which bankers<br />

give preference in disbursing advances <strong>and</strong> the reason <strong>for</strong> the<br />

same;<br />

3. underst<strong>and</strong> lending policies <strong>and</strong> practices In distributing the<br />

loans <strong>at</strong> the branch level; <strong>and</strong>,<br />

4. examine whether the policy of coll<strong>at</strong>eral based lending affects<br />

the flow of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong>.<br />

<strong>at</strong>abase<br />

!lis chapter seeks to address these questions by analysing the<br />

:ound level credit flow <strong>at</strong> bank branch level to different sectors, in<br />

'neral, <strong>and</strong> to <strong>agriculture</strong>, in particular. For the purpose of this<br />

··:ercise, the d<strong>at</strong>a on supply of credit from four different bank<br />

:,lI1ches of Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district <strong>for</strong> the period 1996-97 to 2000-01 have<br />

m extracted (two branches from advanced block <strong>and</strong> the other two


1"'<br />

from backward block based upon some important parameters). The<br />

dl'~ailed<br />

discussion rel<strong>at</strong>ing to the economic background of the<br />

sl'il'Ctcd district <strong>and</strong> blocks is provided below.<br />

Economic Background o/the Selected District <strong>and</strong> Blocks<br />

Tl:e Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district has drawn world-wide <strong>at</strong>tention <strong>for</strong> poverty,<br />

Illiteracy, underdevelopment, starv<strong>at</strong>ion de<strong>at</strong>hs, recurring drought <strong>and</strong><br />

so on. The Government of India, Government of Orissa, Reserve Bank<br />

of India <strong>and</strong> especially N<strong>at</strong>ional Bank <strong>for</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural<br />

De\'c!opment (NABARD) are seriously concerned about the economic<br />

dCl'elopment of the district. W<strong>at</strong>ershed development programme,<br />

promotion of self-help groups <strong>and</strong> linking them with banks <strong>and</strong><br />

?;ot,-iding financial assistance to the st<strong>at</strong>e government <strong>for</strong> the cre<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

of necessary infrastructure are some of the important steps<br />

, uI:dcrtaken by NABARD <strong>for</strong> the economic development of Kalah<strong>and</strong>i<br />

,dIstrict. Since availability of credit is a part of development process,<br />

f\alah<strong>and</strong>i district has been selected <strong>for</strong> this purpose.<br />

laj L<strong>and</strong> Utilis<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

Tc,pographically, Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district is loc<strong>at</strong>ed in the south-western<br />

iJdrt of Orissa. It has two distinct sub-regions: plains <strong>and</strong> hilly tracts.<br />

The total geographical area of the district spreads over 8,493 sq. kms.,<br />

(r)l1lpnsing of 2 sub-divisions <strong>and</strong> 13 blocks. The cultivable l<strong>and</strong> in<br />

"Ill' district falls in three distinct c<strong>at</strong>egories. They are high, medium<br />

,,':ld low l<strong>and</strong>s consisting of 54 per cent, 28 per cent <strong>and</strong> 18 per cent<br />

!I'spcctively of total cultivable l<strong>and</strong> of 393,550 hectares (NABARD<br />

.~IJlJ 1-02). Of the total cultivable area, 46.5 per cent is suitable <strong>for</strong><br />

'j"ddv <strong>and</strong> rest <strong>for</strong> other crops. The main crops grown in the district<br />

;,Il' paddy, minor cereals, pulses, oilseeds, sugarcane, cotton, fruits<br />

{"j Ol1lon.


Ill) L<strong>and</strong> Distribution<br />

The ownership structure <strong>and</strong> management of l<strong>and</strong> determine the st<strong>at</strong>e<br />

of agricultural prosperity <strong>and</strong> equity. A majority of the cultiv<strong>at</strong>ors in<br />

the district are marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers. Around 40 per cent of the<br />

holdings in the district have oper<strong>at</strong>ed area less than one hectare,<br />

\lhile 48 per cent of the total number of holdings derive their<br />

sustenance from holdings ranging between one to four hectares.<br />

Roughly, 30 per cent of the total cultivable area is under the<br />

occup<strong>at</strong>ion of small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers. Importantly, around 12 per<br />

cent of the total number of holdings are medium to large in size<br />

accounting <strong>for</strong> as much as 39 per cent of the total oper<strong>at</strong>ional area<br />

(Table 5.1).<br />

Table 5.1: Size Class-wise Number <strong>and</strong> Area under Oper<strong>at</strong>ional<br />

Hid' mgs<br />

s 0<br />

ize of L<strong>and</strong>holdings Kalah<strong>and</strong>i 1990·1991) Orissa 11990·1991)<br />

No. of Oper<strong>at</strong>ed No. of Oper<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

Holdings Area Holdings Area<br />

-<br />

U o I- 1. 0 (Marginal)<br />

lin '00) (in '00 hect) lin '00) (in '00 hect)<br />

647 (39.9) 369 (11. 7) 21,184 (53.7) 10,451 (19.7)<br />

01-2.0 (Small)<br />

425 (26.2) 588 (18.7) 10,353 (26.2) 14,262 (26.9)<br />

2 .01-4.0 (Semi-medium) 355 (21.9) 951 (30.2) 5,935 (15.0) 15,608 (29.5)<br />

4 01-10.0 (Medium) 175 (l0.8) 982 (31.2) 1,855 (4.7) 10,118 (19.1J_<br />

0.01- Above (Large)<br />

18 (Ll) 260 (8.2) 152 (004) 2,519 (4.8)<br />

T ()~al<br />

1,620 (100) 3,150 (100) 39,479 (100) 52,958 (100)<br />

\o[e: FIgures m parentheses refer to percentages from the correspondmg column<br />

",CIrce: Government of Orissa (1996).<br />

The inequality in the distribution of l<strong>and</strong> ownership in the<br />

dIstrict can be traced to nineteenth century l<strong>and</strong> revenue settlements,<br />

IlhICh led to the emergence of bipolar class structure. At the top of the<br />

Iural hierarchy were the gountias, village headmen who distributed<br />

:dlld <strong>for</strong> cultiv<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> collected l<strong>and</strong> revenue <strong>for</strong> the St<strong>at</strong>e during the<br />

i~rl'-colonial period, <strong>and</strong> whose power was consolid<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>and</strong><br />

"~Itlmised<br />

by the colonial government. Although the gountia system<br />

'.is abolished in 1936, they were allowed to retain large extent of l<strong>and</strong><br />

124


<strong>for</strong> personal cultiv<strong>at</strong>ion (Das 1962). Over time, gountias came to wield<br />

cIa-larger influence over their villages, where they occupied the best<br />

l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> gained control over wastel<strong>and</strong> resources. The ceiling<br />

legisl<strong>at</strong>ion was largely unsuccessful in the redistribution of l<strong>and</strong> from<br />

the nch gountias to the poor l<strong>and</strong>less farmers. As a result, a small<br />

section, which is very well endowed with wealth, exercises control<br />

through credit, l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> labour markets over a large mass of<br />

peasantry, which has been unfavourably placed in so far as the access<br />

to productive assets like l<strong>and</strong>. The gountia system coupled with<br />

dependence of a large proportion of popul<strong>at</strong>ion on <strong>agriculture</strong> resulted<br />

in extreme inequality of l<strong>and</strong> ownership.<br />

Ie) Agrarian Conditions<br />

The normal rainfall in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district is around 1,378 mms.<br />

However, it varied from as low as 1,045.5 mms to as high as 2,011.2<br />

mms between 1994 <strong>and</strong> 1999. The err<strong>at</strong>ic behaviour of the monsoon,<br />

uneven distribution of rainfall during the crop season coupled with<br />

occasional long dry spells <strong>at</strong> post-sowing or pre-productive stage<br />

caused extensive damage to the st<strong>and</strong>ing crops almost in every<br />

eli tcrn<strong>at</strong>ive year.<br />

In the context of uncertain rainfall, the artificial irrig<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

:xIiity assumed an important role. However, on an average, the<br />

percentage of irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area to gross cropped area continued to be<br />

oi!ound 18.5 per cent between 1995-96 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000 (Table 5.2),<br />

"h'Ch is less than the st<strong>at</strong>e average. It shows th<strong>at</strong> around 81.5 per<br />

• ":n of the gross cropped area entirely depended upon rainfall in the<br />

Jii"rict. Out of the total irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area, around 55 per cent of the area<br />

L "Tig<strong>at</strong>ed by major <strong>and</strong> minor projects, <strong>and</strong> the rest by lift irrig<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

125


<strong>and</strong> ram dependent sources like tanks <strong>and</strong> dugwelJ. The irrig<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

areas under major <strong>and</strong> minor projects are confined to Jaip<strong>at</strong>na,<br />

Dharmagarh, Kalampur, Junagarh, <strong>and</strong> Bhawanip<strong>at</strong>na blocks. It is<br />

also mentioned th<strong>at</strong> the existing w<strong>at</strong>er harvesting structure in the<br />

district is found inadequ<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> irrig<strong>at</strong>ing the l<strong>and</strong> coming under the<br />

ayacut area because of low storage of w<strong>at</strong>er in the reservoir <strong>and</strong><br />

absence of l<strong>and</strong> levelling in the adjoining areas (St<strong>at</strong>e Bank of India<br />

2000-01). Consequently, the area under HYV as well as fertiliser<br />

consumption per hectare of gross cropped area in the district is lower<br />

than th<strong>at</strong> of the st<strong>at</strong>e average (Table 5.2).<br />

Table 5.2: Area under Irrig<strong>at</strong>ion, Fertiliser Consumption <strong>and</strong><br />

Area under HYV in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i District <strong>and</strong> Orissa<br />

Year K<strong>at</strong>ah<strong>and</strong>i Orissa<br />

Area Under Area Under Fertlliaer Area Under Area Under Fertiliser<br />

Irription HYVto Con.ump Irrig<strong>at</strong>ion to HYVto Consumpto<br />

Oro .. Oro .. -tlon Gro .. Oross tion<br />

Cropped Cropped Ka/laec Cropped Area Cropped K&/laec<br />

i Area-(%\ Area(%J -,%) Area-'%)<br />

1995-96 15.4 20.6 11 27.2 32.5 25<br />

1996-97 16.2 25.5 15 27.5 38.3 31<br />

1997-98 19.7 27.1 18 26.8 38.4 35<br />

: 1998-99 19.7 27.2 22 28.0 38.8 36<br />

1999-2000 22.0 29.3 28 29.5 42.0 42<br />

: Entire 18.5 25.7 - 27.8 37.8 -<br />

I Period<br />

Source: Government ofOnssa (1995-96,1996-97, 1997-98, 1998-99, <strong>and</strong> 1999-<br />

2000).<br />

(d\ Characteristics of Popul<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> Their Occup<strong>at</strong>ional Distribution<br />

The total popul<strong>at</strong>ion in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i (excluding Nuapada sub-division of<br />

old Kalah<strong>and</strong>i) district was 11.31 lakhs in 1991 with the sex r<strong>at</strong>io of<br />

999 females per thous<strong>and</strong> males. Around 93 per cent of the total<br />

popul<strong>at</strong>ion stay in the rural areas. The percentages of male <strong>and</strong> female<br />

liter<strong>at</strong>es in the district were 31 <strong>and</strong> 8, while those <strong>for</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e were<br />

47 <strong>and</strong> 21 respectively. The proportion of scheduled castes <strong>and</strong><br />

scheduled tribes popul<strong>at</strong>ion was high, around 46 per cent. According


to the 1991 census, the total number of workers in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district<br />

was 4.26 lakh, constituting 37.67 per cent of the total popul<strong>at</strong>ion in<br />

the district. Of the 4.26 lakhs workers, a bulk of them were engaged in<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>. The proportion of cultiv<strong>at</strong>ors in the total work<strong>for</strong>ce was 43<br />

per cent, whereas it was 41.1 per cent in the case of agricultural<br />

labourers (Table 5.3). Since 84 per cent of the total work<strong>for</strong>ce<br />

depended on <strong>agriculture</strong>, <strong>agriculture</strong> could be st<strong>at</strong>ed as the mainstay<br />

of the district's economy.<br />

.<br />

Table 5 3: Socio-Economic Fe<strong>at</strong>ures of Kalah<strong>and</strong>i District<br />

i Geographical area 8439 Sq.Kms. -<br />

I No. of blocks 13 -<br />

No. of villages 2,185 -<br />

I Total popul<strong>at</strong>ion 11.31 lakhs As per 1991 census<br />

. Total number of workers 4.261akhs - do -<br />

f Number of cultiv<strong>at</strong>ors 1.821akhs - do-<br />

1 '7C:: 1_1.1-_<br />

I Num~r of agricultural !.abourers ..... 'oJ U;'.IU.'~ - uui<br />

Length of surface roads 12524 Kms By 1996-97<br />

,_ No. of registered motor vehicles 17,429 Bv 1997-98<br />

i No. of allop<strong>at</strong>hic medical institutions 61 Bv 1996-97<br />

I No. livestock aid centers 129 - do -<br />

No. of livestock inspectors 121 - do -<br />

I No. of financial institutions' 92 Bv 2000-01<br />

Note: * Consists of co-oper<strong>at</strong>Ives, commercial <strong>and</strong> regIOnal TUral banks.<br />

Source: Government of Orissa (1996, 1997).<br />

re) Infrastructure Facilities<br />

Kalah<strong>and</strong>i is the most backward district as far as the availability of<br />

infrastructure facility is concerned. The surfaced roads 4o per 1,000<br />

square kms of geographical area was 1,475 kms in 1997-98. The<br />

condition of the existing roads is bad <strong>and</strong> poorly maintained. The<br />

number of registered motor vehicles per lakh of popul<strong>at</strong>ion (as per the<br />

1991 census) in the district was 1,541 in 1997-98. The number of<br />

buses running between district <strong>and</strong> block headquarters were hardly<br />

41l It includes n<strong>at</strong>ional highways, St<strong>at</strong>e highways, Major district roads, other district<br />

roads, <strong>for</strong>est roads, grama panchay<strong>at</strong> roads, classified village roads, P.S. Roads,<br />

village roads <strong>and</strong> urban roads.


sufficient. In the case of some interior villages, roads were not<br />

connected, <strong>and</strong> public transport system did not exist.<br />

The medical facilities are virtually absent in the villages, <strong>and</strong><br />

['I'en if they exist, the medical staff hardly stay in the villages. For any<br />

kmd of major or minor health problem one has to consult either the<br />

sub-divisional or district headquarter hospitals or priv<strong>at</strong>e doctors. For<br />

instance, the number of allop<strong>at</strong>hic medical institutions 41 per lakh of<br />

pupul<strong>at</strong>ion was 5.4 during 1996-97 in the district. The veterinary<br />

facilities are almost absent in the district. Out of 2,185 villages, only<br />

129 livestock aid centers with 121 livestock inspectors were there in<br />

the district by 1995-96. It shows th<strong>at</strong>, on an average, a single<br />

livestock inspector had to cover 18 vilIag('s. Importantly, cut<br />

total number of villages only 52.7 percentage of villages was electrified<br />

in the district by March 1997.<br />

There were 92 branches of various banks! financial institutions<br />

oper<strong>at</strong>ing in the district including 43 branches of Kalah<strong>and</strong>i Anchalika<br />

Gramya Bank, 35 commercial banks, 11 branches of central cooper<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

bank, 2 Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural Development bank, <strong>and</strong> one<br />

immch of Orissa St<strong>at</strong>e Financial Corpor<strong>at</strong>ion. It is noticed th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

number of people depending upon per branch was 13,600, whereas<br />

the average number of villages covered per bank branch was around<br />

24 111 the district by the year 2001-02 (NABARD 2001-02). This shows<br />

th<strong>at</strong> the average popul<strong>at</strong>ion per bank branch in the district was less<br />

thelD th<strong>at</strong> of St<strong>at</strong>e average, which was 16,300 during 1999-2000.<br />

I, ",,'Iudes district headquarters hospital, sub-divisional hospital, other hospitals,<br />

(ulilmunity health centres, Primary health centres, <strong>and</strong> Mobile health centres.


The existing marketing facilities are insufficient in the district.<br />

Because of poor transport <strong>and</strong> communic<strong>at</strong>ion facilities, a gre<strong>at</strong><br />

majority of the marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers find it inconvenient <strong>and</strong><br />

unprofitable to sell their agricultural produce in the regul<strong>at</strong>ed markets<br />

loc<strong>at</strong>ed in the nearby urban or semi-urban localities. As a result, most<br />

of them sell their produce to the middleman or grain trader in their<br />

villages <strong>at</strong> much lower r<strong>at</strong>es than those prevailing in the regul<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

markets 42 •<br />

It must be emphasised, however, th<strong>at</strong> the economic<br />

backwardness is not uni<strong>for</strong>m in all parts of the district. When<br />

compared with the hilly tracts pursuing rain-fed <strong>agriculture</strong>, the areas<br />

possessing fl<strong>at</strong> <strong>and</strong> fertile paddy -fields receiving w<strong>at</strong>er from Indrav<strong>at</strong>i<br />

river (presently through a dam constructed across the river) permit a<br />

more advanced <strong>for</strong>m of <strong>agriculture</strong>. Of the 13 blocks in the district, six<br />

fall in the advanced region, while the rest in the backward region. The<br />

blocks of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na <strong>and</strong> Narla, on which the study is based, represent<br />

the advanced <strong>and</strong> backward regions, respectively, of Kalah<strong>and</strong>i<br />

district. The differences between the two blocks are evident from the<br />

following details. While the proportion of irrig<strong>at</strong>ed are to gross cropped<br />

area in Jaip<strong>at</strong>na varied between 50 to 58 per cent across the seasons,<br />

the corresponding figures <strong>for</strong> Narla block were 13 to 31 per cent.<br />

Similarly, the fertiliser consumption was only 6 kgs per hectare in<br />

Narla block as compared to the figure of 15 kgs <strong>for</strong> Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block.<br />

" For example, in most of the villages from where primary d<strong>at</strong>a were collected, the<br />

farmers sold their paddy within the range of Rs. 265 to Rs. 325 per bag (75 kg) in<br />

the village when the prevailing r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>at</strong> th<strong>at</strong> time was Rs. 380 in the year 200 \-02.<br />

The study made by Rajasekbar <strong>and</strong> Vyasulu (\993) in the Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district also<br />

mentions a similar kind of rmding. They notice th<strong>at</strong> in one of the sample villages<br />

loc<strong>at</strong>ed just 34 kms away from the district headquarter of Bhawanip<strong>at</strong>na, the<br />

farmer sold paddy <strong>for</strong> Rs. 125 per quintal in the village, while the prevailing r<strong>at</strong>e<br />

<strong>at</strong> th<strong>at</strong> time was Rs. 160.


These differences in agricultural inputs lead to vari<strong>at</strong>ions In the<br />

density of paddy cultiv<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> paddy yield r<strong>at</strong>es. In Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block,<br />

paddy cultiv<strong>at</strong>ion was widespread (with almost 100 per cent in Kharif<br />

season), whereas in Narla it accounted <strong>for</strong> only about 61 per cent of<br />

the area during the same season 43 . The per hectare yield r<strong>at</strong>es <strong>for</strong><br />

paddy were 6 to 14 quintals in the backward <strong>and</strong> advanced blocks,<br />

respectively. There were also infrastructural differences - particularly<br />

with regard to communic<strong>at</strong>ions (measured in terms of the length of<br />

durable roads, <strong>and</strong> popul<strong>at</strong>ion covered by post office <strong>and</strong> banks), - as<br />

well as the number of industries <strong>and</strong> development of off-farm<br />

economic opportunities (Table 5.4).<br />

Although the two blocks in Kala..h.<strong>and</strong>i district differed in terms<br />

of resources, agricultural technology, cropping p<strong>at</strong>tern, yield r<strong>at</strong>es,<br />

communic<strong>at</strong>ions <strong>and</strong> industrial development, the agrarian structure<br />

was largely the same. In each block, there<strong>for</strong>e, it was the gountias <strong>and</strong><br />

large l<strong>and</strong>holders who owned considerable tracts of agricultural l<strong>and</strong>,<br />

having as a result control over credit <strong>and</strong> labour markets as well as<br />

local institutions. At the other end of the agrarian class structure, a<br />

large number of small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers belonging mostly to the<br />

depressed castes depended on tiny l<strong>and</strong>holdings without much access<br />

to institutional credit. It was these smallholders who depended on the<br />

in<strong>for</strong>mal credit market loc<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>at</strong> both village <strong>and</strong> town <strong>levels</strong> <strong>for</strong> their<br />

production <strong>and</strong> consumption needs to a gre<strong>at</strong>er extent.<br />

" The other important crops in Narla block are cotton <strong>and</strong> banana.


Priority Sector Lending<br />

The proportion of credit to priority sector has exp<strong>and</strong>ed significantly<br />

over time in the selected bank branches in both the blocks. In<br />

Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block, although the share of priority sector had marginally<br />

declined from 89.47 to 87.72 per cent from total advance <strong>for</strong> the years<br />

1997 -98 to 1998-99, there was an overall increase in the share of<br />

priority sector in the total advance by 2000-01 (Table 5.5). For Narla<br />

block, it can be observed th<strong>at</strong> there was a continuous increase in the<br />

share of outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit to the priority sector <strong>and</strong> it went up from<br />

76.86 per cent in 1996-97 to 86.04 per cent in 2000-01.<br />

I<br />

,<br />

\<br />

I<br />

Table 5.5: Sector-wise Flow of Bank Credit<br />

(in per cent)<br />

1996- 1997- 1998- 1999- 2000- Annual<br />

Sectors 97 98 99 2000 01 Average<br />

Growth R<strong>at</strong>es<br />

Sample BaDb of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na Block<br />

Agriculture 42.83 37.87 27.83 21.69 18.82 09.69<br />

Other Priority Sector 46.65 50.37 60.00 72.78 76.07 56.40<br />

Total Priority Sector 89.47 88.24 87.72 94.47 94.89 39.28<br />

Non·Priority Sector 10.53 11.76 12.28 5.53 5.11 09.71<br />

I Total Advance<br />

; IRs. in Lakhs} 229.13 262.49 399.27 572.45 740.75 36.70<br />

Sample BaDb of Narla Block<br />

, Agriculture 48.91 41.78 37.53 40.07 46.83 11.69<br />

Other Priority Sector 27.94 36.22 40.76 41.73 39.20 22.79<br />

Total Priority Sector 76.86 78.00 78.29 81.79 86.04 16.27<br />

Non·Priority Sector 23.14 22.00 21.71 18.21 13.96 00.34<br />

I Total Advance<br />

, (Rs, in Lakhs) 87.93 108.94 126.42 134.63 146.59 13.13<br />

Source: Sample Bank Branches of Jlllp<strong>at</strong>na <strong>and</strong> Narla Block<br />

The total volume of outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit disbursed by the<br />

selected bank branches in Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block was Rs. 229.13 lakhs in<br />

1996-97 <strong>and</strong> it increased to Rs. 740.75 lakhs by 2000-01 <strong>at</strong> an<br />

annual growth (in nominal term) r<strong>at</strong>e of 36.70 per cent. In the case of<br />

Narla block, this growth r<strong>at</strong>e was only 16.27 per cent. In both the<br />

blocks, a higher growth r<strong>at</strong>e was not uni<strong>for</strong>m across different sectors<br />

(Table 5.5). Importantly, the higher growth r<strong>at</strong>e of outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit


to the total priority sector (TPS) in both the blocks could be <strong>at</strong>tributed<br />

to the higher growth r<strong>at</strong>e of credit in the other priority sector (OPS)<br />

consisting of small business firms (SBF), small-scale industries (SSI)<br />

<strong>and</strong> so on. The growth r<strong>at</strong>e of credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> was far below<br />

than the growth r<strong>at</strong>e of credit to the OPS, indic<strong>at</strong>ing th<strong>at</strong> the bankers<br />

were giving preference to non-agricultural activities. This situ<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

was more prominent in the advanced block like Jaip<strong>at</strong>na. It implies<br />

th<strong>at</strong> where there is scope to invest in non-<strong>agriculture</strong> sector, banks<br />

are reluctant to extend their credit facility to the agricultural sector. If<br />

we compare the growth r<strong>at</strong>e of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> OPS with the<br />

growth r<strong>at</strong>e of credit to TPS in the selected bank branches of both the<br />

blocks, Narla block has rel<strong>at</strong>ively less scope <strong>for</strong> the banks to deploy<br />

their funds_ in the OPS or non-farm activity. This is due to lower<br />

absorption capacity by the non-farm activity holder or less scope <strong>for</strong><br />

investment in SBF <strong>and</strong> or SSI. In this context, the bankers are of the<br />

view th<strong>at</strong> where there is scope, non-agricultural loans not only have<br />

better recoveries but also fetch rel<strong>at</strong>ively higher interest r<strong>at</strong>es'".<br />

From the <strong>for</strong>egoing discussion one can conclude th<strong>at</strong> the higher<br />

growth r<strong>at</strong>e of credit flow to the OPS has been taking place <strong>at</strong> the cost<br />

of credit going to <strong>agriculture</strong>. This preference of lending <strong>for</strong> nonagricultural<br />

activities can also be corrobor<strong>at</strong>ed by d<strong>at</strong>a on the share of<br />

agricultural credit from total advances. Table 5.5 shows th<strong>at</strong> the per<br />

cent share of advance to <strong>agriculture</strong> from net bank credit has declined<br />

from 42.83 per cent in 1996-97 to 18.82 per cent in 2000-01 in the<br />

case of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block. Besides, there exists a higher gap between the<br />

growth r<strong>at</strong>e of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> total advance (Le. 27.01 per<br />

cent) <strong>for</strong> the same reference period. The same appears to be true in<br />

"' It has been argued th<strong>at</strong> the increasing oper<strong>at</strong>ing costs <strong>and</strong> higher loan<br />

delinquency r<strong>at</strong>es compel the banks to adopt such a str<strong>at</strong>egy (Shylendra \996)_


the case of credit going to <strong>agriculture</strong> in Narla block except <strong>for</strong> the<br />

years 1999-00 <strong>and</strong> 2000-01. Interestingly, although the volume is<br />

less, the proportion of credit going to <strong>agriculture</strong> from total advance in<br />

the backward block (Narla) is more than th<strong>at</strong> of advanced block<br />

(Jaip<strong>at</strong>na) in the last five years. This can be <strong>at</strong>tributed mainly to the<br />

non-availability of scope <strong>for</strong> deployment of funds in the OPS. Hence,<br />

the higher growth r<strong>at</strong>e of credit flow to the TPS <strong>and</strong> or total advance<br />

cannot be <strong>at</strong>tributed to an increase in agricultural <strong>finance</strong>.<br />

Notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing this, within the priority sector, there is a preference<br />

<strong>for</strong> non-<strong>agriculture</strong> sector by the bankers.<br />

Why is it th<strong>at</strong> the growth r<strong>at</strong>e of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> is much<br />

below the growth r<strong>at</strong>e of credit to the TPS? To address this question, it<br />

is essential to review the policies rel<strong>at</strong>ing to the norms of priority<br />

sector lending. Fir<strong>at</strong>, direct <strong>and</strong> indirect c<strong>at</strong>egories of agricultural<br />

advances within the sub-target of 18 per cent of agricultural lending<br />

were clubbed in 1993-4 subject to the stipul<strong>at</strong>ion th<strong>at</strong> 'indirect'<br />

lending to <strong>agriculture</strong> must not exceed one-fourth of the agricultural<br />

target or 4.5 per cent of net bank credit. It had also been decided to<br />

include any indirect advance exceeding 4.5 per cent into the overall<br />

target of priority sector. Second, increasing the ceiling of credit limit<br />

to Rs. 5 lakhs <strong>for</strong> agricultural inputs supply <strong>and</strong> allied to <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

(like dairy, poultry, piggery <strong>and</strong> so on) <strong>and</strong> bringing them under the<br />

purview of indirect agricultural advances. This widened the scope of<br />

the priority sector, in general, <strong>and</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong>, in particular. Third,<br />

the extension of financial facility to even dealers in drip irrig<strong>at</strong>ion,<br />

sprinkler, <strong>and</strong> agricultural machinery was classified as 'indirect<br />

<strong>finance</strong> to <strong>agriculture</strong>'. Nevertheless, short-term advances to<br />

plant<strong>at</strong>ions of tea, coffee, rubber <strong>and</strong> spices, irrespective of the size of


the holdings were brought under the scope of direct agricultural<br />

advances.<br />

As a result of policies rel<strong>at</strong>ing to addition of sub-sectors into the<br />

priority sector lending, the scope of <strong>agriculture</strong> sector is much larger<br />

<strong>at</strong> present than wh<strong>at</strong> it was in the early 1990s. Consequently, the<br />

credit flow has to be channelised to new sub-sectors keeping the limit<br />

<strong>at</strong> 18 per cent. This has led to shrinkage of loans to the initial subsectors<br />

such as agricultural term loan <strong>and</strong> more specifically allied<br />

agricultural activities (Table 5.6).<br />

The broadening of priority sector besides <strong>agriculture</strong> with higher<br />

credit limit is other important factor <strong>for</strong> a high growt..1-J. r<strong>at</strong>e of credit<br />

flow to OPS <strong>and</strong>, in tum, to TPS. For instance, initially, SSI were those<br />

industries whose investment on plant <strong>and</strong> machinery did not exceed<br />

Rs.35 lakhs. In the case of ancillary units, the investment limit was<br />

Rs.45 lakhs. In May 1994, these limits were raised to Rs.60 lakhs <strong>and</strong><br />

Rs.75 lakhs respectively. According to the revised definition, all<br />

advances to SSls were to be tre<strong>at</strong>ed as priority sector lending. Besides,<br />

<strong>for</strong> small units 45 a target of 40 per cent of total credit to SSI was fixed.<br />

Furthermore, the existing ceiling limits on advances to OPS such as<br />

retail trade, small business enterprises, housing, professional <strong>and</strong><br />

self-employed persons under the purview of priority sector advance<br />

were also elev<strong>at</strong>ed. Thus, when the new areas were entered under the<br />

umbrella of priority sector lending, the scope of deployment of funds<br />

by bankers increased to a gre<strong>at</strong>er extent resulting in gre<strong>at</strong>er flow of<br />

credit to OPS <strong>and</strong> also TPS. This proposition can be substanti<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

4S Small units consist of cottage industries, khadi <strong>and</strong> village industries, artisans<br />

<strong>and</strong> tiny industries with investment in plant <strong>and</strong> machinery up to Rs.5 lakhs. For<br />

more detailed in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion, see, RBI (1992-93, 1994).


from the sector-wise flow of outst<strong>and</strong>ing credit (Table 5.5) where nonagricultural<br />

purposes accounted <strong>for</strong> the highest share of total<br />

advances. In this context, it is necessary to examine the p<strong>at</strong>tern of<br />

agricultural lending.<br />

Agricultural Lending<br />

Agricultural loans are advanced <strong>for</strong> three broad purposes, VIZ., crop<br />

production (consisting of agricultural cash credit <strong>and</strong> agricultural gold<br />

loan), agricultural investment, <strong>and</strong> allied activities. The production<br />

credit is generally in the <strong>for</strong>m of short-term loans given <strong>for</strong> various<br />

seasonal agricultural oper<strong>at</strong>ions. The agricultural investment <strong>and</strong><br />

allied activities come under term loans given <strong>for</strong> the purposes like l<strong>and</strong><br />

development, minor irrig<strong>at</strong>ion, farm mechanis<strong>at</strong>ion, <strong>for</strong> the purchase<br />

of draft animals, <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> pursuing activities like dairying, sheep <strong>and</strong><br />

go<strong>at</strong> rearing, etc.<br />

Coming to the flow of agricultural credit, Table 5.6 gives the<br />

purpose-wise share of credit going to <strong>agriculture</strong>. In the case of the<br />

selected bank branches in Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block, credit extended to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> was Rs. 98.13 lakhs in 1996-97 consisting of 42.83 per<br />

cent of total advances. By 2000-01, although the volume of bank<br />

credit to this sector had gone up to Rs.139.44 lakhs, its share from<br />

total advances had come down to 18.82 per cent. Interestingly, on an<br />

average, the volume of credit going to <strong>agriculture</strong> through the selected<br />

banks in Narla block was less than 50 per cent of the volume of credit<br />

going to this sector in Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block <strong>for</strong> the last five years. However,<br />

one can observe a rel<strong>at</strong>ively gre<strong>at</strong>er share of credit from total advances<br />

going to <strong>agriculture</strong> in the backward block (Narla) compared to<br />

advanced block (Jaip<strong>at</strong>na). This phenomenon is being noticed since<br />

1996-97 (Table 5.6). Notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing this, crop production <strong>and</strong>


agricultural term loans (ATL) accounted <strong>for</strong> the highest share of loans<br />

outst<strong>and</strong>ing in <strong>agriculture</strong> in both the areas.<br />

Table 5.6: Purpose-wise Distribution of Agricultural Credit<br />

from 1996-97 to 2000-01<br />

(in per cent)<br />

I Purpose 1996- 1997- 1998- 1999- 2000-<br />

97<br />

I<br />

98 99 2000 01<br />

Sample Banks of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na Block<br />

I<br />

I Agricultural Cash Credit-tAl 33.29 22.79 21.25 22.67 24.60<br />

~ Agricultural Gold loan-fBI 11.16 12.21 18.97 17.49 15.12<br />

Total Croo Loan fA+ BI 44.45 35.00 40.22 40.17 39.72<br />

Agricultural Term Loan 49.13 55.04 55.80 54.88 50.36<br />

Allied to Agriculture 06.42 09.96 03.98 04.95 09.92<br />

Total Advance (Rs. in Lakhsl 98.13 99.40 110.71 124.15 139.44<br />

I<br />

Sample Banks of Narla Block<br />

, Agricultural Cash Credit-fA) 20.41 19.67 18.12 21.06 29.18<br />

I Agricultural Gold Loan- (B) 14.65 16.39 13.57 19.50 17.31<br />

l10tal Crop Loan (A+BI 35.06 36.06 31.70 40.56 46.48<br />

I Agricultural Term Loan 36.39 38.15 38.57 31.02 31.87<br />

I Allied to Agriculture 28.55 25.80 29.74 28.42 21.65<br />

, Total Advance (Rs. in Lakhs) 43.01 45.51 45.51 47.45 53.94<br />

Source: Sample Bank Branches of JB1p<strong>at</strong>na <strong>and</strong> Narla Block<br />

Based on the above discussion on the credit going to <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

by banks in both the areas, one can raise an important question. Why<br />

is th<strong>at</strong> the proportion of credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> from net bank credit<br />

is rel<strong>at</strong>ively more in backward area as compared to the advanced one?<br />

Wh<strong>at</strong> accounts <strong>for</strong> a gre<strong>at</strong>er share of credit to crop production <strong>and</strong><br />

investment loans? From the lenders' perspective, one can argue th<strong>at</strong><br />

since better altern<strong>at</strong>ive opportunities are available in non-agricultural<br />

activities in advance areas, the deployment of funds to <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

may not be <strong>at</strong>tractive. Altern<strong>at</strong>ively, less opportunity <strong>for</strong> investment in<br />

non-<strong>agriculture</strong> sector may <strong>for</strong>ce the bankers to tum to <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

investment. This argument seems to be true from a substantial low<br />

growth r<strong>at</strong>e of credit flow to OPS in the backward region compared to<br />

the advanced one rrable 5.5). Nevertheless, low (gre<strong>at</strong>er) share of<br />

credit going to <strong>agriculture</strong> from net bank credit may be due to low


[high) repayment r<strong>at</strong>e of loan by the borrower in the concerned sector.<br />

Hence, in order to explore more about the issues, it is essential to<br />

examine sector-wise recovery to dem<strong>and</strong>.<br />

Table 5.7: Sector-wise Recovery of Loan Amount to Dem<strong>and</strong><br />

(in per cent)<br />

1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-2000 2000-01<br />

Sectors<br />

Jaip<strong>at</strong>na Block<br />

: Agrl. Loan 62.92 63.20 66.00 65.17 59.87<br />

· <strong>for</strong> Agrl 23.88 33.50 32.12 20.86 23.17<br />

-!ric_ulture 40.99 45.38 45.17 43.54 40.17<br />

)n-<strong>agriculture</strong> 69.79 78.51 80.73 69.93 71.62<br />

·:al 57.89 63.38 63.43 59.49 60.22<br />

Narla Block<br />

:-::1· Agrl. Loan 58.21 60.38 59.02 70.70 60.85<br />

· <strong>for</strong> Agrl 26.28 34.54 37.48 41.05 22.40<br />

lJ'iculture 40.75 51.44 52.85 62.28 49.40<br />

',:1-<strong>agriculture</strong> 67.37 54.71 50.00 63.79 70.18<br />

,._'tal 49.65 52.51 41.01 6271 , SS 7? ,<br />

S,)urce: Sample Bank Branches of Jalp<strong>at</strong>na <strong>and</strong> Narla Block<br />

Table 5.7 shows th<strong>at</strong> there is an improvement 111 terms of<br />

rel'overy to dem<strong>and</strong>, especially in non-<strong>agriculture</strong> sector in both the<br />

regions. The percentage of total recovery increased from 57.89 per<br />

cellt in 1996-97 to 60.22 per cent in 2000-01 in the selected bank<br />

brclnches of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block. This can be <strong>at</strong>tributed to higher recovery<br />

rale 111 the non-agricultural sector compared to <strong>agriculture</strong>.<br />

Fl,nhermore, the percentage of recovery <strong>for</strong> the entire sector (both<br />

"gr:C'ulture <strong>and</strong> non-<strong>agriculture</strong>) to total dem<strong>and</strong> shows th<strong>at</strong> the r<strong>at</strong>e<br />

of repayment was more in the selected bank branches of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na<br />

b;,. k as compared to Narla Block except <strong>for</strong> the year 1999-00.<br />

HIJ\\TVer, in the l<strong>at</strong>ter block, the r<strong>at</strong>e of recovery of amount lent to<br />

agrll'ulture as a proportion to dem<strong>and</strong> was always higher than th<strong>at</strong> in<br />

thl' <strong>for</strong>mer block <strong>for</strong> the entire period. This high recovery r<strong>at</strong>e rna\' be<br />

,J:;,' of the important contributing factors <strong>for</strong> a gre<strong>at</strong>er share of credit<br />

gOlt:" to <strong>agriculture</strong> from total net bank credit in the case of Narla


lock. Based on the above discussion, one can raise the following<br />

questions. Wh<strong>at</strong> contributes to low recovery r<strong>at</strong>e in the agricultural<br />

sector in the advanced Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block? Is the low repayment more<br />

prevalent in short-term or term loans to <strong>agriculture</strong>?<br />

To underst<strong>and</strong> the questions addressed here, it is essential to<br />

examine the repayment r<strong>at</strong>e of both short-term <strong>and</strong> term loans <strong>for</strong><br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>. Table 5.7 shows th<strong>at</strong> there was high repayment r<strong>at</strong>e In<br />

short-term (ST) loans compared to long-term agricultural loans In<br />

both the blocks. However, there was a growing tendency in the<br />

repayment r<strong>at</strong>e in short-term agricultural loans <strong>for</strong> the period 1996-97<br />

to 1998-99 in the selected bank branches of both the regions. A<br />

ckclining tendency of repayment in ST !oa.'1S could be obser .... ed from<br />

the year 1999-00 onwards in both the areas. Interestingly, the low<br />

repayment r<strong>at</strong>e of long-term (LT) loans is a common phenomenon in<br />

both the blocks. This indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> the low repayment r<strong>at</strong>e of<br />

agricultural loans as a whole in Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block could be <strong>at</strong>tributed to<br />

rel<strong>at</strong>ively poor repayment of term loans.<br />

Why is the repayment r<strong>at</strong>e of long-term agricultural loan so<br />

poor? Wh<strong>at</strong> may be the contributing factors <strong>for</strong> declining tendency of<br />

repayment <strong>for</strong> crop loans (ST loan)? To underst<strong>and</strong> the questions<br />

addressed here, one need to undertake a <strong>micro</strong>-level (households)<br />

analysis. In the context of the above issues, the farmers are of the<br />

opinion th<strong>at</strong> under <strong>finance</strong>, diversion, <strong>and</strong> misutilis<strong>at</strong>ion of funds are<br />

the major factors which adversely affect the repayment r<strong>at</strong>e.<br />

Taking into account the repayment r<strong>at</strong>e of both <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

non-<strong>agriculture</strong> sectors, one can ask, whether the share of credit to<br />

139


<strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>for</strong>m total advance by banks is positively rel<strong>at</strong>ed with the<br />

interest income 46 on advance? Table 5.8 reveals th<strong>at</strong> the interest<br />

income on advance is more in the selected bank branches of the<br />

Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block <strong>for</strong> the last four years (1997-98 to 2000-011, where the<br />

share of credit going to <strong>agriculture</strong> has been decreasing continuously,<br />

<strong>and</strong> this share is less as compared to the counterpart region. In this<br />

context, one can arrive <strong>at</strong> a conclusion th<strong>at</strong> given the repayment r<strong>at</strong>e,<br />

interest income on advance is inversely rel<strong>at</strong>ed with the flow of credit<br />

going to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector.<br />

Table 5.8: Interest Income on Advance<br />

(in per cent)<br />

ParticuJara<br />

Years<br />

1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-2000 2000·01<br />

--- -<br />

Selected Bal·lk Branchcs<br />

: of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na Block 6.16 9.65 8.89 9.23 10.94<br />

I Selected Bank Branches<br />

~arlaBlock<br />

7.37 7.74 8.84 8.91 8.38<br />

Source: Sample Bank Branches of J<strong>at</strong>p<strong>at</strong>na <strong>and</strong> Narla Block<br />

It can be inferred th<strong>at</strong> the credit norms rel<strong>at</strong>ing to profitability is<br />

one of the important contributing factors <strong>for</strong> lower credit flow to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>. Thus, if the interest income is gre<strong>at</strong>er than or <strong>at</strong> least<br />

equal to the cost of lending (wh<strong>at</strong> is termed as break-even level of<br />

interest4 7 ), this may positively influence the financial institutions to<br />

increase the supply of credit. However, default r<strong>at</strong>e plays an important<br />

role in determining the break-even level of interest r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> a financial<br />

institution. Higher the default r<strong>at</strong>e, higher is the break-even interest<br />

r<strong>at</strong>e th<strong>at</strong> has to be charged. But, given the administr<strong>at</strong>ive interest<br />

"Income = (Interest Received on Advance I Total Advance by Bank) x 100.<br />

,; It implies the minimum needed lending r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> the bank (i.e. Income from loan<br />

portfolio ~ Cost of lending). For more details, see, Anderson <strong>and</strong> Khamb<strong>at</strong>a<br />

(1985), Hulme <strong>and</strong> Morsely (1996) <strong>and</strong> S<strong>at</strong>ish <strong>and</strong> Gopalkrishna (1997).<br />

140


141<br />

r<strong>at</strong>e, banks cannot increase their lending r<strong>at</strong>es. There<strong>for</strong>e, banks will<br />

try to bring down the break-even condition of lending r<strong>at</strong>e to<br />

reasonable <strong>levels</strong> by reducing default r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> the cost of lending. In<br />

our case, since the separ<strong>at</strong>e figure of interest income on only<br />

agricultural lending is not available <strong>at</strong> the branch level, we have taken<br />

interest income on total advance as the proxy variable to explain its<br />

rel<strong>at</strong>ion with the flow of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong>. It is observed th<strong>at</strong> <strong>for</strong> the<br />

bank branches where the interest income on advance is more (<strong>for</strong><br />

instance, the selected bank branches of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na Block), the share of<br />

credit going to <strong>agriculture</strong> out of total deployment is less <strong>and</strong> viceversa.<br />

Security Based Lending<br />

In general, bank loans are sanctioned on the basis of four different<br />

types of security. They are: l<strong>and</strong>, gold, deposits, <strong>and</strong> hypothec<strong>at</strong>ion of<br />

loan assets <strong>and</strong> personal security. The loan sanctioned with l<strong>and</strong> as<br />

security can be further sub-divided into (i) sanction of loan by<br />

mortgage, <strong>and</strong> (iiI loans by a charge over l<strong>and</strong>. Basically, the <strong>for</strong>mer<br />

type of security is needed <strong>for</strong> agricultural term loan like improvement<br />

of l<strong>and</strong>, purchase of agricultural implements, development of minor<br />

irrig<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> so on. In the case of default of loans, which are<br />

sanctioned on the basis of mortgage type of security, the l<strong>and</strong> may be<br />

sold <strong>for</strong> recovering the dues. To meet the requirement of working<br />

capital in crop production the l<strong>at</strong>ter type of security is needed <strong>and</strong> the<br />

dues have to be recovered only out of the proceeds of the l<strong>and</strong>.<br />

However, the borrower has to produce the record of ownership right<br />

over the said l<strong>and</strong> to obtain loan against both c<strong>at</strong>egories of l<strong>and</strong><br />

security. In the case of loans with l<strong>and</strong> as security, the amount of<br />

loan obtained depends on the cost of the said project, value of l<strong>and</strong> if<br />

It is an investment loan, <strong>and</strong> the scale of <strong>finance</strong> if it is crop loan.


142<br />

Loan sanctioned on the basis of either gold or deposits as security can<br />

be tre<strong>at</strong>ed as dem<strong>and</strong> loan. The amount of loan sanctioned depends<br />

upon the market value of the gold ornaments subject to the maximum<br />

amount fixed per unit. In the case of default, the bank can auction the<br />

particular ornaments to recover the dues with advance notice to the<br />

borrower. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, any default of loan against deposit will<br />

be adjusted <strong>at</strong> the time of repayment. In the context of loan<br />

sanctioned against hypothec<strong>at</strong>ion of loan assets <strong>and</strong> personal<br />

security, no primary coll<strong>at</strong>eral is needed as explained above. This type<br />

of loan sanction helps the borrower who cannot af<strong>for</strong>d any primary<br />

coll<strong>at</strong>eral to access institutional credit <strong>and</strong> if the loan is sanctioned <strong>for</strong><br />

asset cre<strong>at</strong>ion, the same works as coll<strong>at</strong>eral <strong>for</strong> the bank till the loan<br />

is repaid. In the case of default, the hypothec<strong>at</strong>ed asset may be sold<br />

<strong>for</strong> repayment. In the case of loan against personal security, the<br />

borrower is expected to repay the loan on dem<strong>and</strong> by the banks. This<br />

type of loan basically plays a major role <strong>at</strong> the time of sanction in nonfarm<br />

activity.<br />

With this background, it may be necessary to know the<br />

distribution of agricultural credit by type of security. Since the return<br />

on agricultural investment is highly uncertain <strong>and</strong> affected by several<br />

factors, <strong>and</strong> the probability of default r<strong>at</strong>e is high, the financial<br />

institutions may be reluctant to extend credit facility to the<br />

agricultural sector. Thus, to minimise the lending risk, the bankers<br />

may prefer coll<strong>at</strong>eral based lending.


Table 5.9: Distribution of Agricultural Credit by Type of<br />

Security<br />

(in per cent)<br />

Type of Security 1996·97 1997·98 1998·99 1999· 2000·0il<br />

2000<br />

Sample Banks of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na Block<br />

L<strong>and</strong> 47.64 31.40 44.10 32.38 41.07<br />

· Gold 11.16 12.21 18.97 17.49 15.12<br />

· Hypothec<strong>at</strong>ion of Loan Assets 41.20 56.39 36.93 50.12 43.80<br />

· <strong>and</strong> Personal Security<br />

~otal Advance IRs. in Lakhs) 98.13 99.40 110.71 124.15 139.44<br />

,<br />

Sample Banks of Narla Block<br />

, L<strong>and</strong> 55.29 51.00 58.48 56.47 65.39<br />

, Gold 14.69 16.39 13.57 19.50 17.31<br />

Hypothec<strong>at</strong>ion of Loan Assets 30.02 22.61 27.95 24.03 17.31<br />

<strong>and</strong> Personal Security<br />

Total Advance (Rs. in Lakhs) 43.01 45.51 47.45 53.94 68.65<br />

Source: Sample Bank Branches of Jrup<strong>at</strong>na <strong>and</strong> Narla Block<br />

It may be noted from Table 5.9 th<strong>at</strong> a major percentage of total<br />

amounts of loan is given on the basis of security of l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> gold (in<br />

both the regions). However, the proportion of loans given on the basis<br />

of hypothec<strong>at</strong>ion of loan assets <strong>and</strong> personal security have also<br />

accounted <strong>for</strong> a significant share in the total outst<strong>and</strong>ing advance to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> in Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block. In the last five years (Le., from 1996-97<br />

to 2000-01), loan disbursed against hypothec<strong>at</strong>ed loan assets <strong>and</strong><br />

personal security ranged from 37 to 56 per cent of total loan<br />

outst<strong>and</strong>ing in the sample bank branches of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block. Given the<br />

backwardness, the r<strong>at</strong>e of disbursement of loan against hypothec<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

loan assets <strong>and</strong> personal security is supposed to be more in the<br />

backward region like Narla. Surprisingly, the r<strong>at</strong>e of disbursement of<br />

loan against these securities vary from the range of as low as 17 per<br />

cent to as high as 30 per cent of total credit given <strong>for</strong> agricultural<br />

purposes in the sample bank branches of Narla block. It must be<br />

emphasised, however, th<strong>at</strong> the proportion of total agricultural credit<br />

disbursed against hypothec<strong>at</strong>ion of loan assets <strong>and</strong> personal security<br />

is less in the selected bank branches of backward block compared to


the advanced block (Table 5.9). Thus, is it true th<strong>at</strong> the bankers are<br />

really extending their credit facility <strong>at</strong> a significant r<strong>at</strong>e on the basis of<br />

hypothec<strong>at</strong>ion of loan assets <strong>and</strong> personal security in the service area<br />

of selected bank branches of advanced block?<br />

It is known th<strong>at</strong> a loan against hypothec<strong>at</strong>ion of assets <strong>and</strong><br />

personal security is supposed to be sanctioned without insisting on<br />

any coll<strong>at</strong>eral under various credit-based poverty allevi<strong>at</strong>ion schemes.<br />

Earlier, it has been argued th<strong>at</strong> the bank followed both direct <strong>and</strong><br />

indirect coll<strong>at</strong>eral based lending except in the case of poverty<br />

allevi<strong>at</strong>ion schemes under which it was compelled to lend without<br />

insisting on any coll<strong>at</strong>eral (Shylendra 1996). For instance, in many<br />

cases it is found th<strong>at</strong>, although, no coll<strong>at</strong>eral security except<br />

hypothec<strong>at</strong>ion of loan assets <strong>and</strong> personal security is to be considered<br />

on paper, <strong>for</strong> loans other than schem<strong>at</strong>ic fmance, in practice the<br />

banks are sanctioning such loans only to those borrowers who<br />

borrowed some secured loans by pledging l<strong>and</strong> or gold or maintaining<br />

some term deposit in the bank. Hence, borrowers' opinion may look<br />

more logical to underst<strong>and</strong> this problem.<br />

Following are some of the important problems of the borrowers<br />

th<strong>at</strong> have been observed in the field area of Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district who<br />

had taken loans under allied agricultural activities. First, under this<br />

c<strong>at</strong>egory of loans, the bankers kept <strong>at</strong> least some amount out of<br />

subsidy given (in some cases the whole subsidy amount) in the <strong>for</strong>m of<br />

deposit in the bank against the concerned borrower. It implies th<strong>at</strong>, in<br />

the case of default, the deposit amount is adjusted <strong>at</strong> the time of<br />

repayment. Altern<strong>at</strong>ively, in the worst situ<strong>at</strong>ion, the bank can recover<br />

<strong>at</strong> least part of total dues from the deposit amount of the concerned


orrower. Thus, one can deduce th<strong>at</strong> under <strong>finance</strong> is a common<br />

fe<strong>at</strong>ure in the case of loans th<strong>at</strong> fall under the c<strong>at</strong>egory of allied<br />

agricultural activities. Second, banks in general release the loan in<br />

more than one instalment either in the <strong>for</strong>m of cash or kind or both.<br />

Under this circumstance, if there is no substantial utilis<strong>at</strong>ion of<br />

released amount, the bankers stop releasing the balance amount of<br />

loan <strong>for</strong> the concerned project. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, this unutilised<br />

amount may be deposited in the bank by opening a new account<br />

against the concerned borrower. Hence, in the light of the abovementioned<br />

point, one can assume th<strong>at</strong> bankers always take up both<br />

direct <strong>and</strong> or indirect <strong>for</strong>m of coll<strong>at</strong>eral from the borrowers who fall<br />

under the c<strong>at</strong>egory of other than schem<strong>at</strong>ic <strong>finance</strong>.<br />

Coming back to the selected bank branches of Narla block,<br />

Table 5.9 shows the loan given on the basis of l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> gold security<br />

accounted <strong>for</strong> about <strong>at</strong> least 70 per cent of the total outst<strong>and</strong>ing loans<br />

during the period 1996-97 to 2000-01. This indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> the flow of<br />

agricultural credit is largely governed by the security th<strong>at</strong> the stock of<br />

capital (Le., assets like l<strong>and</strong> or gold) offers to the financial institutions<br />

advancing credit r<strong>at</strong>her than by the factors influencing the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

credit. One can conclude, there<strong>for</strong>e, th<strong>at</strong> to some extent coll<strong>at</strong>eral<br />

based lending affects the flow of institutional credit to the <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

sector.<br />

Inter-Regional Differences in Priority Sector Lending <strong>and</strong><br />

Deposits<br />

Table 5.10 shows th<strong>at</strong> during the period 1996 to 2001, priority sector<br />

credit as a proportion of total bank deposits (PSCBD) had gone up<br />

from 64.64 per cent in 1996 to 116.7 per cent in 2001 in Jaip<strong>at</strong>na<br />

, ..


'4"<br />

block. Surprisingly, PSCBD has always been less than th<strong>at</strong> of 'priority<br />

sector credit as a proportion of bank credit (PSCBC) except <strong>for</strong> the<br />

year 2000-01. However, the reverse is true in the case of Narla block<br />

except <strong>for</strong> the years 1999-2000 <strong>and</strong> 2000-01. This indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

per<strong>for</strong>mance of selected bank branches of Narla block in terms of<br />

mobilis<strong>at</strong>ion of deposits on priority sector lending was much better<br />

during the period 1996-97 to 1998-99 r<strong>at</strong>her than the period 1999-<br />

2000 to 2000-01. Thus, as long as PSCBD is gre<strong>at</strong>er than PSCBC, one<br />

can suggest th<strong>at</strong> there is better per<strong>for</strong>mance by banks so far as the<br />

mobilis<strong>at</strong>ion of deposits under the service area of the bank is<br />

concerned. On the contrary, if PSCBD is less than PSCBC, it implies<br />

th<strong>at</strong> there is less credit flow to priority sector out of loanable funds<br />

<strong>for</strong> institutional credit, if PSCBD is less than PSCBC of a particular<br />

bank branch, then any initi<strong>at</strong>ive measures by the bankers <strong>for</strong> a<br />

positive movement of the first r<strong>at</strong>io can facilit<strong>at</strong>e more supply of credit<br />

in the service areas.<br />

.<br />

Table 5.10: Proportion of Priority Sector Lending to Total<br />

Credit <strong>and</strong> Total De )Oalts<br />

, Sample 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-2000<br />

PSC·<br />

SO<br />

I Banks psc· PSC· PSC· psc. psc· PSC· PSC·<br />

BC BD BC BD BC BD BC<br />

I Jaip<strong>at</strong>na<br />

Block<br />

[Narla<br />

Block<br />

89.47<br />

76.86<br />

64.64<br />

105.30<br />

88.24<br />

78.01<br />

66.17<br />

92.49<br />

87.72<br />

78.29<br />

85.55<br />

81.56<br />

94.47<br />

81.79<br />

Note. PSCBC - Pnonty Sector Credlt as Proportlon of Bank Credlt<br />

PSCBD· Priority Sector Credit as Proportion of Bank Deposits<br />

Source: Sample Bank Branches of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na <strong>and</strong> Narla Block<br />

86.85<br />

76.27<br />

2000-01<br />

PSC· PSC·<br />

BC<br />

so<br />

94.89 116.70<br />

86.04 72.35<br />

During the period 1996-97 to 2000-01, loans to <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

sector by banks as a proportion of total bank deposits have been<br />

invariably declined in both the regions except a marginal improvement<br />

in the last year, i.e., 2000-01. In the case of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block,<br />

agricultural credit as proportion of bank deposits (AGLCBD) was lower


to AGLCBC (Agricultural Credit as Proportion of Bank Credit) <strong>for</strong><br />

almost all the referred years except <strong>for</strong> the year 2000-01 .<br />

Furthermore, the r<strong>at</strong>io AGLCBD perpetually declined from 30.94 per<br />

cent in 1996-97 to 23.15 per cent in 2000-01. It is, there<strong>for</strong>e, one can<br />

say th<strong>at</strong> the amount of credit going to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector out of total<br />

deposits from the sample bank branches of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block was not<br />

encouraging. It seems banks were diverting their loanable funds to<br />

non-agricultural sector. This finding can be corrobor<strong>at</strong>ed with a<br />

substantial high growth r<strong>at</strong>e of credit flow to other priority sectors<br />

(excluding <strong>agriculture</strong>) in Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block (Table 5.5).<br />

In so far as Narla block is concerned, the r<strong>at</strong>io AGLCBD was<br />

more than AGLCBC <strong>for</strong> the years 1996-97 to 1998 99 (Table 5.11).<br />

However, the reverse trend could be observed <strong>for</strong> the remaining years<br />

starting from 1999-2000 to 2000-01. The r<strong>at</strong>io AGLCBD declined from<br />

67.01 per cent <strong>for</strong> the year 1996-97 to 39.38 per cent by 2000-0l.<br />

This indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> although the volume of deposits in the bank was<br />

increasing, this had not induced any stimul<strong>at</strong>ion in the flow of<br />

agricultural credit.<br />

Table 5.11: Proportion of Lending to Agriculture from Total<br />

C re d· It an d TID ota epOSl ·t S<br />

isamPle 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01<br />

Banks AGLC AGLC AGLC AGLC AGLC AGLC AGLC AGLC AGLC AGLC<br />

BC BD BC BD BC BD BC BD BC BD<br />

': .Jalp<strong>at</strong>na<br />

. Biock 42.83 30.94 37.87 28.40 27.83 27.04 21.69 19.94 18.82 23.15<br />

\arla Block<br />

48.91 67.01 41.78 49.53 37.53 39.10 40.07 37.36 46.83 39.38<br />

\ote. AGLCBC- Agncultural Credlt as Proporhon of Bank Credlt<br />

AGLCBD· Agricultural Credit as Proportion of Bank Deposits<br />

Source: Sample Bank Branches of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na <strong>and</strong> Narla Block.<br />

The key findings emerging from an analysis of priority sector<br />

lending <strong>and</strong> deposits (see Graph 1) <strong>at</strong> the bank branch <strong>levels</strong> of both<br />

lhe blocks are the following:


• The credit given to priority sector as a proportion of total bank<br />

credit <strong>and</strong> deposits have been increasing in the advanced block.<br />

• The PSCBD r<strong>at</strong>io in the service area of sample bank branches in<br />

the backward Narla block have been declining <strong>for</strong> the last five<br />

years, <strong>and</strong> it is less than the PSCBD r<strong>at</strong>io of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block since<br />

1998-99. This indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> bankers are having better opportunity<br />

to mobilise their funds raised by deposits on priority sector in the<br />

advanced region. The poor infrastructure <strong>and</strong> lack of scope <strong>for</strong> nonfarm<br />

activities can be <strong>at</strong>tributed to the poor absorption capacity of<br />

credit by the potential borrowers in the case of backward regions<br />

like Narla.<br />

• A comparison of PSCBC r<strong>at</strong>io between the bank branches of both<br />

the regions further confirm the argument th<strong>at</strong> bankers are having<br />

more scope <strong>for</strong> priority sector lending in the advanced region.<br />

Graph 1: PSCBD <strong>and</strong> PSCBC in the Sample Bank Branches of<br />

Jaip<strong>at</strong>na <strong>and</strong> Narla Block<br />

~~~ [<br />

PSCBO <strong>and</strong> PSCBC in the sample banI< branches of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na <strong>and</strong> Narla<br />

.-_________ BIOCk<br />

._u________ .~<br />

..?<br />

'--,<br />

~-".~-~--!<br />

1:~r=_~<br />

- ~..;;....;.~r"'"---'':'~-~:<br />

~--<br />

~ 70 ...:::;:,.;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;.........-::--------------<br />

u 60 --,- ---- - ________, -\<br />

Ii;<br />

Cl. 50 1----------------------------<br />

40 \----------.---------------.<br />

30 I<br />

,<br />

201---------------------------,<br />

10<br />

o<br />

1<br />

L-______________________________________ _<br />

1997 1998 1999<br />

Year<br />

*<br />

2000 2001<br />

__ PSCBDJ ..... -- PSCBCJ -..-PSCBDN PSCBCN<br />

Note: PSCBDJ: Priority sector credit as proportion to total bank deposits in<br />

sam pie bank branches of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block.<br />

PSCBCJ: Priority sector credit as proportion of bank credit in sample<br />

bank branches of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block.<br />

PSCBDN: Priority sector credit as proportion to total bank deposits in<br />

sampl~ bank branches of :-;arla block.<br />

PSCBCJ: Priority sector credit as proportion of bank credit in sample<br />

bank branches of Narla block.<br />

I-IS


However, an increasing or decreasing proportion of credit flow to<br />

priority sector out of total bank credit or deposits will not necessarily<br />

be accompanied by an increasing or decreasing share of credit to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> sector. Our analysis suggests th<strong>at</strong> although more <strong>and</strong><br />

more proportion of total bank credit is disbursed to priority sector as a<br />

whole over a period of time, the share of <strong>agriculture</strong> sector from net<br />

bank credit has been declining in both the regions. A comparison of<br />

AGLCBD <strong>and</strong> AGLCBC r<strong>at</strong>ios between two regions (Graph 2) put the<br />

following observ<strong>at</strong>ions:<br />

• The AGLCBD r<strong>at</strong>io is declining in the service area of sample bank<br />

branches <strong>for</strong> both the blocks over a period of time. Surprisingly,<br />

the AGLCBD r<strong>at</strong>ios in the bank branches of backward block were<br />

more than th<strong>at</strong> _ _" of _____ thp Rriv~nrprl ___ . _____ hlnr-lr __ ~ ___ ..................... fnr thp ~nt-;T"""" ......... ~ .." ...... ""o pv~&U"'" .... ~"'~ ..... ->t..UlLlll5<br />

+ ..... - ~ ...... --<br />

from 1996-97 to 2000-01. It implies th<strong>at</strong> the banks in the<br />

backward region were mobilising a higher proportion of their<br />

deposits <strong>for</strong> agricultural lending compared to the banks in the<br />

advanced region. This supports our previOUS finding of higher<br />

growth r<strong>at</strong>e of agricultural credit in the backward region compared<br />

to the advanced one.<br />

• A higher AGLCBC r<strong>at</strong>io of backward blocks indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> branches<br />

were showing their interest to disburse a higher proportion of net<br />

bank credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector compared to the advanced one.<br />

Given the risk on agricultural lending, there<strong>for</strong>e, th<strong>at</strong> the coll<strong>at</strong>eral<br />

based lending policies were more prominent in the service areas of<br />

banks in the backward regions (see Table 5.9).<br />

149


Graph 2: AGLCBD <strong>and</strong> AGLCBC in the Sample Bank Branches<br />

of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na <strong>and</strong> NarIa Block<br />

-c:<br />

CII<br />

0<br />

"- 30<br />

CII<br />

a..<br />

20<br />

10<br />

•<br />

...<br />

0<br />

1997 1998 1999 2000 2001<br />

Year<br />

-+-AGLCBDJ -4-AGLCBCJ --.--.AGLCBDN<br />

AGLCBCN<br />

Note: AGLCBDJ: Agricultural credit as proportion to bank credit in sample<br />

bank branches of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block<br />

AGLCBC: Agricultural credit as proportion to total bank credit in<br />

sample bank branches of Jaip<strong>at</strong>na block<br />

AGLCBDN: Agricultural credit as proportion to bank credit in sample<br />

bank branches of NarJa block<br />

AGLCBN: Agricultural credit as proportion to total bank credit in<br />

sample bank branches of NarJa block<br />

Conclusions<br />

This chapter concentr<strong>at</strong>ed on an analysis of the impact of broadening<br />

the coverage of priority sectors on credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>at</strong> the<br />

bank branch level in developed <strong>and</strong> backward blocks in the selected<br />

district. The key findings are th<strong>at</strong> the share of priority sector from<br />

total bank advance had increased in both the regions, whereas the<br />

share of credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> had declined during the same<br />

period. Thus, the higher growth r<strong>at</strong>e of credit to priority sector as a<br />

whole was due to a higher growth r<strong>at</strong>e of credit disbursed to sectors 48<br />

" Activities covered under this sector include (i) Transport oper<strong>at</strong>ors, (ii) Retail trade<br />

<strong>and</strong> Small Business, (iii) Professional <strong>and</strong> Self Employed, (iv) Educ<strong>at</strong>ional Loans,<br />

(v) Housing Loans, (I) Consumption loans (g) Small Scale Industries, <strong>and</strong> (h)<br />

Miscellaneous activities (NABARD 2001-02).


other than the <strong>agriculture</strong> within the priority sector. It indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong><br />

the bankers were giving preference to non-agricultural activities. This<br />

was widespread phenomenon in the service area of banks in the<br />

advanced region.<br />

It is observed th<strong>at</strong> the quantum of supply of agricultural credit<br />

(in absolute figures) in the service area of selected bank branches in<br />

the advanced region was almost two times of credit disbursed to this<br />

sector in the backward regions <strong>for</strong> the last five years. However, a<br />

rel<strong>at</strong>ively gre<strong>at</strong>er share of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> from total advances was<br />

observed in the backward block comparee! to the advanced one. Two<br />

Important indic<strong>at</strong>ors, viz., interest income on advance <strong>and</strong> type of<br />

security-wise supply of agricultural credit was adopted in the analysis<br />

to examine this. A comparison between the two regions on interest<br />

income on total advance <strong>and</strong> the proportion of credit going to <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

from the total amount of loan was found to be inversely rel<strong>at</strong>ed. In<br />

other words, <strong>for</strong> the bank branches where the proportion of total bank<br />

credit was found more <strong>for</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> sector, their interest income was<br />

found to be less <strong>and</strong> vice-versa. It is also observed th<strong>at</strong> the flow of<br />

ugricultural credit was largely governed by the coll<strong>at</strong>eral security (l<strong>and</strong><br />

or gold) th<strong>at</strong> the stock of capital offers to the financial institutions<br />

odvancing credit r<strong>at</strong>her than by the factors influencing the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

credit. Not surprisingly, more the proportion of total advance <strong>for</strong><br />

awicultural credit, more prominent was the <strong>for</strong>m of coll<strong>at</strong>eral based<br />

lending.<br />

Inter-regional disparities in the flow of credit to the priority<br />

"·ctor, in general, <strong>and</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong>, in particular, as a proportion of the<br />

t'll,\l deposit in the bank is a common phenomenon in the


institutional credit markets. Any analysis of inter-regional differences<br />

in priority sector lending from net bank credit (PSCBC) <strong>and</strong> deposits<br />

(PSCBD), in general, <strong>and</strong> agricultural lending to total bank credit<br />

(AGLCBC) <strong>and</strong> deposits (AGLCBD), in particular, were undertaken <strong>for</strong><br />

both the regions. In a region, where PSCBD was gre<strong>at</strong>er than PSCBC,<br />

it indic<strong>at</strong>es a better per<strong>for</strong>mance of banks in the mobilis<strong>at</strong>ion of<br />

deposits from the concerned service area <strong>for</strong> priority sector lending.<br />

On the contrary, if PSCBD was less than PSCBC, it implied th<strong>at</strong> there<br />

was less credit flow to priority sector out of loanable funds gener<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

in the <strong>for</strong>m of the bank deposits. Hence, given the positive dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

institutional credit, if PSCBD was less than PSCBC in a particular<br />

bank branch, then any initi<strong>at</strong>ive by the bankers to step up the first<br />

r<strong>at</strong>io would result in more supply of credit in the service area.<br />

There<strong>for</strong>e, one can suggest th<strong>at</strong> since the quantum of credit disbursed<br />

to the priority sector is calcul<strong>at</strong>ed as a percentage of net bank credit<br />

disbursed, this may not reflect the actual <strong>and</strong> complete picture <strong>for</strong> the<br />

region where PSCBD is less than the PSCBC. Further, if PSCBD is less<br />

than PSCBC, bankers may not be achieving the sectoral targets. Hence,<br />

specific target based on deposit should be made <strong>for</strong> the service area of<br />

c'ach bank.<br />

Based on the interest income on advance <strong>and</strong> the lenders'<br />

expect<strong>at</strong>ion of return on agricultural lending, <strong>and</strong> the policy of<br />

coll<strong>at</strong>eral based lending, it is observed th<strong>at</strong> these factors affected the<br />

C


Chapter 6<br />

VARIATIONS IN THE FLOW OF CREDIT TO FARM<br />

HOUSEHOLDS: A MICRO LEVEL ANALYSIS<br />

Introduction<br />

Poor access to institutional credit by peasant farmers In India (<strong>and</strong><br />

elsewhere) is one of the important fe<strong>at</strong>ur~s in the <strong>for</strong>mal credit<br />

market. The empirical studies show th<strong>at</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal credit is accessed<br />

more by the well to do among the rural people <strong>and</strong> have seldom<br />

benefited the poorer farmers (Rao 1975; Lipton 1976; Adams <strong>and</strong><br />

Vogel 1986). It has also been shown th<strong>at</strong> the distribution of <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

sector credit has been unequal with respect to region, class, <strong>and</strong> caste<br />

(Ramach<strong>and</strong>ran <strong>and</strong> Swamin<strong>at</strong>han 2001). Thus, despite ma.Jor<br />

structural changes in credit institutions in terms of outreach <strong>and</strong><br />

directed credit policy system, the poor access to institutional credit<br />

has been an outst<strong>and</strong>ing problem <strong>for</strong> the gre<strong>at</strong> majority of farm<br />

households. In this context, an <strong>at</strong>tempt has been made to examine the<br />

disparities in the flow of credit to different c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers <strong>and</strong><br />

analyse the factors th<strong>at</strong> contribute to these disparities.<br />

Flow of credit can be examined from two different angles. First,<br />

now of credit viewed from the supply side can be said to depend upon<br />

the security offered <strong>and</strong> the lender's assessment as regards the<br />

[cpayment capacity of the borrower. However, from the borrower's<br />

perspective it is the borrowing capacity'9 th<strong>at</strong> influences the access to<br />

fr)rmal credit. This suggests th<strong>at</strong> the actual flow of credit depends on<br />

Capacity to take a loan refers to the household's capacity to meet the <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

selection criteria <strong>and</strong> banker's additional expect<strong>at</strong>ion on repa~'ment capacity. In<br />

order to win over the lender's confidence, the borrower must be in a pO::)ltion to<br />

s<strong>at</strong>isfy the lender with some coll<strong>at</strong>eral both tangible <strong>and</strong> Intangible.


the factors governing both the supply <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit. S1l1ce<br />

access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit is not common to all farmers, it is necessary to<br />

analyse the factors th<strong>at</strong> account <strong>for</strong> vari<strong>at</strong>ions in the supply of<br />

agricultural credit, Even if some farmers are accessing <strong>for</strong>mal credit, it<br />

may not be sufficient to meet their requirement. If the disbursed loan<br />

amount is largely influenced by the supply-side factors, a larger gap<br />

between the supply <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit is the likely possibility.<br />

Furthermore, the magnitude of this gap may vary across different size<br />

classes of l<strong>and</strong>holdings. The issue of credit-gap across the size of<br />

l<strong>and</strong>holdings has been taken up in Chapter-VII. In this chapter, an<br />

<strong>at</strong>tempt has been made to examine the factors th<strong>at</strong> account <strong>for</strong><br />

vari<strong>at</strong>ions in the flow of credit <strong>at</strong> the household level. It is to be noted<br />

th<strong>at</strong> the vari<strong>at</strong>ions in the flow of institutional credit is possible in tenns<br />

of both access <strong>and</strong> amount obtained. Thus, the analysis of these issues<br />

is essential to underst<strong>and</strong> the agrarian credit market in the study<br />

area.<br />

N<strong>at</strong>ure of Credit Dem<strong>and</strong> of Different C<strong>at</strong>egories of Farmers<br />

The n<strong>at</strong>ure of credit needed by different c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers can be<br />

explained from the <strong>micro</strong> level analysis on the flow of credit to<br />

"griculture. Broadly, farm households can be grouped under four<br />

. lasses. The first sub-c<strong>at</strong>egory includes marginal farmers (owning less<br />

than 2.5 acres of l<strong>and</strong>), who belongs to the bottom range in terms of<br />

:ncome <strong>and</strong> asset holdings. They are partly involved in seasonal<br />

'~riculture<br />

:~om<br />

both as labourers <strong>and</strong> cultiv<strong>at</strong>ors. Since the subsistence<br />

tiny holdings is difficult, they are involved as labourers in non­<br />

:.Irm activities like <strong>for</strong>estry, mining, construction, transport, <strong>and</strong><br />

)ttage <strong>and</strong> small-scale industries. Inadequ<strong>at</strong>e income of this c<strong>at</strong>e~or\"<br />

: farmers compels them to go <strong>for</strong> consumption credit during the slack


months. They also need credit to meet contingent consumption,<br />

working capital, <strong>and</strong> to purchase small productive assets, which are<br />

important in providing supplementary income. This sub-group obtains<br />

credit basically under poverty allevi<strong>at</strong>ion scheme.<br />

The second sub-c<strong>at</strong>egory (owning between 2.51 <strong>and</strong> 5 acres of<br />

l<strong>and</strong>) includes small farmer households. Although <strong>agriculture</strong> is the<br />

main source of their livelihood, they derive a part of their income from<br />

wage employment in farm <strong>and</strong> non-farm activities. Even if this<br />

c<strong>at</strong>egory of farm households occasionally faces shortfalls to meet their<br />

consumption expenditure (including contingent consumption), they<br />

need credit mainly to meet the working capital needs of their<br />

production activities. Nevertheless, they also require additional credit<br />

to acquire agricultural assets such as livestock, small tools <strong>and</strong><br />

machines, pump set, bore wells <strong>and</strong> so on. Farmers under this subc<strong>at</strong>egory<br />

meet their credit needs partly by hypothec<strong>at</strong>ion of loan assets<br />

<strong>and</strong> personal security, <strong>and</strong> partly by providing coll<strong>at</strong>eral security like<br />

l<strong>and</strong>, gold, etc.<br />

Generally, the third <strong>and</strong> fourth subc<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers Iviz.,<br />

;nedium (owning 5.01-10 acres of l<strong>and</strong>) <strong>and</strong> large size (owning more<br />

chan 10 acres of l<strong>and</strong>) farmersJ fall under the affluent section of farm<br />

households. They go <strong>for</strong> commercial production of crops given their<br />

('eonomic st<strong>at</strong>us. Along with farm activity they also engage themselves<br />

Jrl allied <strong>and</strong> non-farm activities like animal husb<strong>and</strong>ry, fishery, farm<strong>for</strong>estry,<br />

agro-processing, manufacturing, trading, re-Iending, etc.<br />

C;lven the economic st<strong>at</strong>us, these c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers have a steady<br />

li


It can be inferred from the <strong>for</strong>egoing discussion th<strong>at</strong> credit is<br />

necessary (may be in different magnitudes) <strong>for</strong> almost all the<br />

c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers to meet their requirements as well as <strong>for</strong> their<br />

future economic development. This study has adopted the<br />

str<strong>at</strong>ific<strong>at</strong>ion discussed above to analyse the credit flow to different<br />

c<strong>at</strong>egories of farm households from the <strong>for</strong>mal financial institutions.<br />

Since issues on agricultural term loan <strong>and</strong> allied to <strong>agriculture</strong> had<br />

been discussed in chapters 4th <strong>and</strong> 5 th , in this chapter focus has been<br />

given to the production credit (short-term loan) given by the banks to<br />

meet the working capital needs of different c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers.<br />

Sources of D<strong>at</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Econometric Methodology<br />

D<strong>at</strong>a Base <strong>and</strong> the R<strong>at</strong>ionale of Sample Selection<br />

As has been noted, there is a tendency <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal credit to flow<br />

towards agriculturally more developed regions <strong>and</strong> to rel<strong>at</strong>ively larger<br />

farmers, leaving the backward regions <strong>and</strong> small farmers to the<br />

in<strong>for</strong>mal market. Accordingly, d<strong>at</strong>a from the service area of four<br />

different bank branches <strong>for</strong> two such regions have been collected to<br />

analyse the p<strong>at</strong>terns in access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit. In the present studv,<br />

the level of technologySO used has been considered as a proxy variable<br />

to define the advanced <strong>and</strong> backward regions. Based on this indic<strong>at</strong>or,<br />

the blocks of the Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district have been c<strong>at</strong>egorised into two<br />

clifferent groups, the two blocks - Jaip<strong>at</strong>na (from the advanced group)<br />

;1nd Narla (from the backward group) - have been r<strong>and</strong>omly selected.<br />

()ne CB <strong>and</strong> one RRB have been r<strong>and</strong>omly chosen from each block.<br />

From the service area of each bank, on the basis of the number of<br />

borrowers in the last three years, the villages have been grouped.<br />

ConsumptlOn of fertiliser per acre of gross cropped area has been usccl as prox:,<br />

!or the level of technology usecl.


Among these groups, in turn, one village group has been picked <strong>at</strong><br />

r<strong>and</strong>om, <strong>and</strong> a sample of fifty borrower households (th<strong>at</strong> is, a farmer<br />

who has borrowed <strong>at</strong> least once during the period 1999-2002) has<br />

been r<strong>and</strong>omly selected. In order to avoid the problem of under or<br />

overrepresent<strong>at</strong>ion, each group of villages has been chosen on the<br />

basis of having approxim<strong>at</strong>ely the same popul<strong>at</strong>ion size. Since peasant<br />

farmers in the research area rarely get crop loans during the Rabi<br />

session, the analysis is restricted to the Kharif crop <strong>for</strong> the year 2001-<br />

02. The per acre paid-out cost of production <strong>for</strong> all c<strong>at</strong>egories of<br />

farmers has been calcul<strong>at</strong>ed in rel<strong>at</strong>ion to the existing technology, so<br />

as to ascertain the extent of production costs met by <strong>for</strong>mal <strong>and</strong><br />

in<strong>for</strong>mal credit sources.<br />

Econometric Methodology<br />

The use of probability models IS conceptually preferable to<br />

conventional linear regression models when the dependent variable is<br />

dichotomous, because parameter estim<strong>at</strong>es from the <strong>for</strong>mer overcome<br />

most weaknesses of linear probability models. In other words, they<br />

provide parameter estim<strong>at</strong>es, which are asymptotically consistent <strong>and</strong><br />

efficient. In this chapter, a Pro bit model has been employed to study<br />

rhe determinants of access to credit. The general model is a binary<br />

choice model involving estim<strong>at</strong>ion of the probability of access to credit<br />

Iy) as a function of a vector of explan<strong>at</strong>ory variable (x). It is assumed<br />

th<strong>at</strong> there is an underlying response variable y" defined by the<br />

regression rel<strong>at</strong>ionship<br />

• 13' }' = x +u<br />

, "<br />

(1)<br />

In practice, y'j is unobservable, wh<strong>at</strong> we observe is a dummy variable<br />

!f defined by<br />

y= 1 if y',>O (access to credit)<br />

=0 othen.vise (not access to credit) (2)


From the above rel<strong>at</strong>ions, we get<br />

Prob (Yi= access to credit) = Prob (u;>-fJ'x;)<br />

= l-F(-fJ'x,} (3)<br />

where F is the cumul<strong>at</strong>ive distribution function <strong>for</strong> u. In this case, the<br />

observed values of y are just realis<strong>at</strong>ions of a binomial process with<br />

probabilities given by equ<strong>at</strong>ion (3) <strong>and</strong> varying from trial to trail<br />

(depending on xil. Hence the likelihood function is<br />

L = IT F(-/I'x, )IT[I-F(-/I'x,)] (4)<br />

),.0 yR"1<br />

Taking the logarithm of L <strong>and</strong> maximising with respect to p, which<br />

gives the ML estim<strong>at</strong>or of slope coefficient.<br />

Sample Selection Bias<br />

Basically, determinants of credit equ<strong>at</strong>ions are estim<strong>at</strong>ed using a subsample<br />

of farmers who have access to credit. Although this may lead<br />

to sample selection bias, Heckman (1979) developed a joint maximum<br />

likelihood procedure to correct this. The procedure involves estim<strong>at</strong>ing<br />

both the probability of access to credit <strong>and</strong> amount of credit obtained<br />

simultaneously. Since this approach requires identific<strong>at</strong>ion of the<br />

credit equ<strong>at</strong>ion, actual size of l<strong>and</strong>holding has been used as the<br />

appropri<strong>at</strong>e variable. For example, peasant farmers who have access<br />

to credit, however, are not a r<strong>and</strong>omly selected sample of all farmers<br />

in the popul<strong>at</strong>ion. Heckman (1979) developed a solution (two-step<br />

procedure) to this problem, <strong>and</strong> this solution variable (Inverse Mills<br />

R<strong>at</strong>io (IMR)) will be added as an explan<strong>at</strong>ory variable in the credit<br />

function to tackle the problem of selectivity bias. To <strong>for</strong>malise the<br />

above explan<strong>at</strong>ion, let the equ<strong>at</strong>ion th<strong>at</strong> determines the sample<br />

selection be<br />

[' , - r 'Z,+u;


<strong>and</strong> let the equ<strong>at</strong>ion of primary interest (determinants of credit) be<br />

The sample selection rule is th<strong>at</strong> y is observed only when I is gre<strong>at</strong>er<br />

than zero. Suppose, as well th<strong>at</strong> E <strong>and</strong> u have a bivari<strong>at</strong>e normal<br />

distribution with zero mean <strong>and</strong> correl<strong>at</strong>ion p, then we may write the<br />

model as<br />

EfYi I Yi is observed] = EfYi I ri >OJ<br />

= E[Yi I Ui > -r ' ZJ<br />

= fJ'Xi + E[Ci I Uj >-r 'ZJ<br />

= fJ'Xi.+p Ue A.i (au)<br />

=fJ'Xi + fJ~A.j (au)<br />

Where ex .. y' Z; / au<br />

<strong>and</strong> l(a.)<br />

;(y'Z,Iu,)<br />

",(y' Z,I u.)<br />

1j II; > 0 = ElY,II; > 0] + v,<br />

.. fJ' Xi + fJ1A., (a,) + V,<br />

Analysing the determinants of credit using the Ordinary Least<br />

Squares regression <strong>for</strong> farmers who had access to credit produces<br />

inconsistent estim<strong>at</strong>es of ~. We can view this problem as omitted<br />

variable. So, least squares regression of y on x <strong>and</strong> A. would produce<br />

consistent estim<strong>at</strong>es, but if A. is omitted, the specific<strong>at</strong>ion error of an<br />

omitted variable is committed. Based on this observ<strong>at</strong>ion, Heckman<br />

proposes a two stage procedures. In the first stage, the discrete choice<br />

model is estim<strong>at</strong>ed by Probit on the entire sample. Using the<br />

estim<strong>at</strong>es, the lambda has been estim<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>and</strong> included in the second<br />

stage estim<strong>at</strong>es of the structural rel<strong>at</strong>ionship on the selected sample<br />

of non-censored observ<strong>at</strong>ions.


Emerging P<strong>at</strong>terns in Rural Credit Market<br />

Of the 200 sample farm households, 86 per cent of them depended on<br />

credit (th<strong>at</strong> is, from both <strong>for</strong>mal <strong>and</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sources) to undertake<br />

agricultural production. However, only 56 per cent of the cultiv<strong>at</strong>ing<br />

households borrowed from <strong>for</strong>mal credit institutions during the<br />

reference year (Table 6.1). But, this proportion varied across the<br />

l<strong>and</strong>holding c<strong>at</strong>egories from as low as 19.4 per cent in the case of<br />

marginal farmers to as high as 81 per cent in the case of medium <strong>and</strong><br />

large size farmers. This underlines the degree to which the proportion<br />

of households borrowing from <strong>for</strong>mal institutions rose in conjunction<br />

with an increase in the size of l<strong>and</strong>holding. Table 6.1 also shows the<br />

extent to which farmers also depended on the in<strong>for</strong>mal credit market.<br />

il shows a positive associ<strong>at</strong>ion between SIZe of l<strong>and</strong>holding <strong>and</strong> the<br />

proportion of households depending on in<strong>for</strong>mal sector except the<br />

large size farmers. Importantly, the proportion of <strong>for</strong>mal borrowers<br />

who had additionally taken out in<strong>for</strong>mal loans also increased with<br />

respect to size of l<strong>and</strong>holding, again with the exception of the large<br />

farm c<strong>at</strong>egory. Based on in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion contained in Table 6.1, the<br />

following inference can be drawn:<br />

(1) the credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning favours larger farm households th<strong>at</strong> are<br />

economically sound <strong>and</strong> in turn the access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit; <strong>and</strong><br />

(2) even if farmers who are accessing credit from <strong>for</strong>mal sources, the<br />

amount obtained is inadequ<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> their requirement, necessit<strong>at</strong>ing<br />

to depend on in<strong>for</strong>mal sector.


Table 6.1: Distribution of Borrowers br Farm Size 12001-02)<br />

Farm Size in Acres)<br />

0.01- 2.51 - 5.00 5.01 - 10.01 <strong>and</strong> Total I<br />

2.50 (Small) 10.00 Above I<br />

(Mare:inal1 (Medium) (Large) i<br />

All Households" 67 (33. 5) 50125.0) 47 123. 51 36118 0) 20011001 •<br />

.<br />

All Borrowers 42 48 47 35 172<br />

% to Total (62.7) (96. 0) (100) (97.21 (86.01<br />

Households<br />

Formal Borrowers 13 32 38 29 112<br />

% to Total (19.4) (64.0) (80.9) (80.6) (56.0)<br />

Households<br />

In<strong>for</strong>mal Borrowers 36 38 43 22 139<br />

% to Total (52.9) (77.6) (91. 5) (61. 1) 169.51<br />

. households<br />

No. of Formal 8 21 34 16 79<br />

! Borrower taken<br />

! In<strong>for</strong>mal Loan (57. 1\' (67.7\" 189. 5\" 155. 2)' (70. 5)'<br />

Note: 1) The figures In parenthesIs In row (U) are percentages of farm households In<br />

each c<strong>at</strong>egory from the total sample of 200.<br />

2) The figures in parenthesis in each cell are the percentages of farm<br />

households from the respective group total.<br />

3) The figures in parenthesis as indic<strong>at</strong>ed by (.) represent the percentages of<br />

households borrowing from <strong>for</strong>mal institutions wh<strong>at</strong> have also taken<br />

in<strong>for</strong>mal loans with respect to the farm size c<strong>at</strong>egory. This gives us the per<br />

cent of <strong>for</strong>mal borrowers in each farm size c<strong>at</strong>egory depending on in<strong>for</strong>mal<br />

credit market.<br />

Source: Field Survey<br />

,<br />

:<br />

,<br />

I<br />

,<br />

,<br />

i<br />

Table 6.2 indic<strong>at</strong>es the vari<strong>at</strong>ion In the share of total<br />

institutional credit among different c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers. In the case<br />

of marginal farmers, who constituted 33.5 per cent of the total sample<br />

of farm households, obtained 4.2 per cent of the total credit<br />

disbursed. The medium c<strong>at</strong>egory farmers, consisting of 23.5 per cent<br />

of the sample households, obtained 30.4 per cent of total <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

credit. It is interesting to note th<strong>at</strong> 47.2 per cent of the funds made<br />

available through <strong>for</strong>mal credit had gone to the large size farmers.<br />

This shows th<strong>at</strong> a small proportion of the total farmers in the sample<br />

vJllage accessed loans from financial institutions (only 56 %), <strong>and</strong><br />

among these a small group consisting of medium <strong>and</strong> large sIze


I<br />

I<br />

farmers engrossed a lion's share of the net volume of credit disbursed.<br />

The above evidence confinns th<strong>at</strong> in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district - as elsewhere<br />

in India - institutional credit tended to gravit<strong>at</strong>e towards the better-off<br />

fanners. These findings are also corrobor<strong>at</strong>ed by some of the earlier<br />

studies [see Lele 1981; Gonzalez-Vega 1984; Adams <strong>and</strong> Vogel 1986;<br />

Braveman <strong>and</strong> Guasch 1986; Egger 1986; Sarap 1990; <strong>and</strong> Basu<br />

1997).<br />

Table 6.2: Distribution of Loan by Farm Size in the Year 2001-<br />

02<br />

(in per cent)<br />

Farm Size (in Acres)<br />

0.01 - 2.50 2.51 - 5. 00 ' 5.01 - 10.00 10.01 <strong>and</strong><br />

(Marginal, (Small' (Medium, Above<br />

ILarge)<br />

I Proportion of Formal Loans 45. 5 68. 6 55. 3 72.5<br />

I to Total Loan Borrowed<br />

Proportion of Formal Credit<br />

obtained by the Group to 4. 2 18. 2 30. 4 47. 2<br />

Total Formal Credit<br />

Source: F,eld survey<br />

Hence, the undeniable expansion of institutional lending in the<br />

rural areas has failed to reach the marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers.<br />

Notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing the policy of lending r<strong>at</strong>e deregul<strong>at</strong>ion 51 , <strong>and</strong> the<br />

measures suggested by Gupta Committee 52 [1998) aimed <strong>at</strong> improving<br />

the quality of credit delivery system in rural areas, CBs have failed to<br />

cover marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers, in general, <strong>and</strong> to increase the<br />

credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector, in particular. This, in turn, raises a<br />

" Since the interest r<strong>at</strong>e charged was unable to cover the cost of lending (i.e.,<br />

financial, transaction <strong>and</strong> risk costs), lending r<strong>at</strong>e of RRB was deregul<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>for</strong> all<br />

sizes of credit limit from August 1996. Prior to this, lending r<strong>at</strong>es of CBs were also<br />

deregul<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>for</strong> credit limit of over Rs. 2 lakhs since August 1994.<br />

S2 The Gupta Committee was set up in 1998 52 to look into the quality of credit<br />

delivered by the banking system, to identify the constraints faced by CBs in<br />

increasing the flow of credit, introduce new product <strong>and</strong> services, <strong>and</strong> simplify<br />

procedures to enable rural borrowers to access adequ<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> timely agricultural<br />

credit from CBs.


<strong>at</strong>her obvious question: why do some farm households have access to<br />

institutional credit while others do not? This issue has been discussed<br />

in the subsequent section.<br />

Table 6.3 shows th<strong>at</strong> out of 200 sample households, only 48<br />

farmers had access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit to grow kharif crops <strong>for</strong> three<br />

times during the last three years. Of the 48 farmers, almost 68.5 per<br />

cent belonged to medium <strong>and</strong> large c<strong>at</strong>egories, while the rest belonged<br />

to marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmer c<strong>at</strong>egories. In the case of access to credit<br />

<strong>for</strong> two times during the reference period also, the number of medium<br />

<strong>and</strong> large size farmers were rel<strong>at</strong>ively more as compared to small <strong>and</strong><br />

marginal farmers. However, the frequency of one time credit obtained<br />

was more in the l<strong>at</strong>ter group of farmers than the <strong>for</strong>mer one. As can<br />

be seen from Table 6.3, the frequency of accessing <strong>for</strong>mal credit by<br />

small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmer was rel<strong>at</strong>ively less than the big size<br />

farmers. The number of times credit obtained is positively associ<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

with the size of l<strong>and</strong> holding.<br />

Table 6.3: L<strong>and</strong>holding-wise Number of Times Crop Loans<br />

(Kharif) Obtained by Farmers <strong>for</strong> the Period 1999 - 2000 to<br />

2001- 2002<br />

(in per cent)<br />

Size or No. or Farmers 3 Time. 2 Time. 1 Time<br />

L<strong>and</strong>holding; in the GrouL<br />

Up to S.OO Acres 117 15 12 45<br />

J31.2) (37.5) (60.81<br />

5.01 Acres <strong>and</strong> 83 33 20 29<br />

Above (68.8) (62.5) (39.2)<br />

Total 200 48 32 74<br />

jl001 (1001 (100)<br />

Note: The figures In parentheSIS are In percentage tenns. Because of poor irrig<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

facility. fanners hardly grew the Rabi crop. Poor support of agricultural<br />

extension seIVices restricts the fanner to go <strong>for</strong> high yielding variety of cash<br />

crop. Thus. bankers hardly provide any loan during Rabi season.<br />

Source: Field Survey


Table 6.4 reveals th<strong>at</strong> the loan amount per acre of gross cropped<br />

area varied across size class of l<strong>and</strong>holdings within <strong>and</strong> across the<br />

regions. The farmers in the advanced region obtained, on an average,<br />

Rs.l,249 per acre of gross cropped area, whereas it was only RS.915<br />

in the backward region. Based on the in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion from Tables 6.3 <strong>and</strong><br />

6.4, it can be argued th<strong>at</strong> there was vari<strong>at</strong>ion in terms of both access<br />

to credit as well as amount of credit obtained from institutional<br />

sources. The contributing factors <strong>for</strong> these vari<strong>at</strong>ions have been<br />

discussed in the subsequent sections.<br />

Table 6.4: Supply of Credit (Crop Loan) Per Hectare of Gross<br />

Cropped Area<br />

(in Rupees\<br />

Size ClaD or Advanced Backward<br />

L<strong>and</strong>holdin&& (in Acres) Region Region<br />

0.01- 2. 50 475 435<br />

2.51 - 5. 00 1 193 1,176<br />

5.01 - 10.00 1308 865<br />

lO.OI <strong>and</strong> Above 1347 927<br />

L All Classes 1,249 915<br />

Source: Field survey<br />

I<br />

Factors Affecting Access to Formal Credit<br />

Since credit transaction necessarily involves a time gap between a<br />

point when the advance is made <strong>and</strong> a future point when credit is<br />

repaid with interest, anything may happen in-between these two time<br />

points. Examined from the lender's viewpoint, the act of borrowing is<br />

one, which carries both pre-contractual (<strong>at</strong> the point prior to credit is<br />

given), <strong>and</strong> post-contractual problems (<strong>at</strong> the point when credit is<br />

repaid). The <strong>for</strong>mer difficulties take the <strong>for</strong>m of adverse selection (i.e.,<br />

the fear of selecting a bad borrower), creditworthiness <strong>and</strong> screening<br />

of the borrower. In the l<strong>at</strong>ter case, a lender faces the problem of wilful<br />

<strong>and</strong> non-wilful default. Given these problems, wh<strong>at</strong> governs access to<br />

institutional credit by some peasant households but not others?


It should be stressed th<strong>at</strong> access to credit is influenced both by<br />

the farmer's capacity to take a loan <strong>and</strong> the lender's willingness to<br />

extend it. This exchange usually involves a signalling <strong>and</strong> screening<br />

procedure in order to communic<strong>at</strong>e in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion about the riskiness of<br />

the loan (Petrick <strong>and</strong> L<strong>at</strong>ruffe 2003). In this context, the farmers'<br />

access to institutional credit is estim<strong>at</strong>ed by using a Probit Model<br />

where the dependent variable Yj is a dichotomous (1, 0) variable<br />

indic<strong>at</strong>ing whether the i-th farm household has access to credit or not.<br />

So, the dummy dependent variable = 1, if the farm household had<br />

access to a loan from <strong>for</strong>mal sources, <strong>and</strong> = 0, otherwise.<br />

It is assumed th<strong>at</strong> the access to agricultural credit is<br />

determined by a number of farm <strong>and</strong> household characteristics. Since<br />

loans are advanced to farmers-who-borrow on the basis of l<strong>and</strong> they<br />

own, the l<strong>at</strong>ter functions as coll<strong>at</strong>eral from the lender's point of view.<br />

Hence, the actual size of l<strong>and</strong> holding can be taken as one of the<br />

important factors governing access to institutional credit. The l<strong>and</strong><br />

quality also improves the !ann household's prospect of obtaining loan.<br />

Better the quality of l<strong>and</strong>, more likely the prospect of a farm<br />

household's access to a loan. Apart from l<strong>and</strong>, other valuable assets -<br />

particularly agriculturaI implements, <strong>and</strong> the proportion of non-farm<br />

income to total income can be used as an indic<strong>at</strong>or to judge the<br />

creditworthiness of the borrower. Indeed, bankers may prefer a<br />

borrower who has income sources apart from an agricultural one so<br />

as to minimise wh<strong>at</strong> they see as the risk of non-repayment. These two<br />

variables are expected to positively influence the access to credit. An<br />

assured source of irrig<strong>at</strong>ion th<strong>at</strong> added to the reliability of crop<br />

production <strong>and</strong> yield is similarly perceived by banks in a positive light,<br />

<strong>and</strong> thus as a contributory factor to borrower credit-worthiness. Thus,


the percentage of irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area to gross cropped area is expected to be<br />

positively associ<strong>at</strong>ed with access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit. Another issue is th<strong>at</strong><br />

the credit-disbursing officials may discrimin<strong>at</strong>e against lower caste<br />

<strong>and</strong> tribal households because they have fewer outside connections<br />

<strong>and</strong> higher caste decision-makers dominant in the credit institutions.<br />

Accordingly, the caste variable is expected to be neg<strong>at</strong>ively correl<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

with access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit facility. Conversely, <strong>for</strong>mal educ<strong>at</strong>ion may<br />

have a positive influence on access to credit. The definition <strong>and</strong><br />

descriptive st<strong>at</strong>istics of the variables used in the analysis are provided<br />

in Table 6.5.<br />

Table 6.5: Definition, Measurement, Descriptive St<strong>at</strong>istics,<br />

<strong>and</strong> EXl»ected Sign of Variables Used in the Probit Equ<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

All Farmers ~ar,,::~n~~& ! Medium &<br />

Variable Description Expeeted I:tmau :'lZe Large Size<br />

Sip<br />

Farmers farmers<br />

Mean Mean Mean<br />

Dep. Var Access to Credit -1; 0, 0.560 0.385 0.81<br />

• otherwise 10.50) (0.49) (0.40)<br />

ASLH Actual size of l<strong>and</strong>holding (in + ve 6.25 2.47 II. 58<br />

I LANDQ<br />

Acre~ (6.20) (I. 56) ~6. 3B)<br />

L<strong>and</strong> quality + ve 0.505 0.28 0.82<br />

- 1, <strong>for</strong> good l<strong>and</strong> quality • (0.50) (0.45) (0.39)<br />

- 0 otherwise<br />

IASSET Value of assets excluding + ye 1,547. 18 2,450.68 33,813.31<br />

l<strong>and</strong> (in Rupees) (47,362. 02) (3,260.52J J69,651.3~<br />

IEOFA Income excluding own farm + ve 35.64 47.79 lB. 50<br />

activity as proportion to total (32.11) (33. 17) (20.95)<br />

family income (in Rupeesl<br />

PIAGCA Percentage of irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area to + ye 22.92 16. 17 32.44<br />

~oss cr~d area 136.29L J32. I~ 139.70)<br />

CASTE Caste st<strong>at</strong>us - ye 0.38 0.49 O. 22<br />

-1 ,if the borrower belong to (0.49) (0. 50) (0.41)<br />

SC or ST<br />

= 0, otherwise<br />

EDU Educ<strong>at</strong>ional quaIific<strong>at</strong>ion of<br />

I the borrower + ye 0.21 0.08 0.40<br />

I<br />

- 1, <strong>for</strong> 10'" or more st<strong>and</strong>ard (0. 41) (0.27) (0.49)<br />

- 0, otherwise<br />

, Number of Observ<strong>at</strong>ions 200 117 B3<br />

~ote. 11) • L<strong>and</strong> particulars were collected from each <strong>and</strong> every farmer 10 terms a f a rea ( in<br />

Acres) under low, medium <strong>and</strong> high in the survey. It IS found th<strong>at</strong> the high l<strong>and</strong><br />

was completely rain fed <strong>and</strong> the probability of crop failure was more. In the case of<br />

low l<strong>and</strong> the possibility of crop failure was minimal. Under this assumption,. If the<br />

area under low l<strong>and</strong> was covering <strong>at</strong> least one third of total l<strong>and</strong> owned, It was<br />

considered as farmer having good quality l<strong>and</strong>.<br />

(2) Figures in parentheses indic<strong>at</strong>e St<strong>and</strong>ard Devi<strong>at</strong>ion.


Table 6.6: Access to Formal Credit: Pro bit Results<br />

IDummy Dependent Variable = I, if the farm household has access to credit: = O.<br />

Otherwisel<br />

r Variables All Farmers Marginal <strong>and</strong> Small Medium <strong>and</strong> Large<br />

I<br />

Size Farmers<br />

Size Farmers<br />

I Coefficient Marginal Coefficient<br />

1 Marginal Coefficient Marginal . i<br />

Effect Effect ._ Effect.J<br />

I Constant 0.33221' 0.19000 -0.0026 - 0.00091 - 0.08633 - 0.00056 \<br />

i<br />

12.12) 1- 0.01) (- 0 16)<br />

-<br />

! ASLH -0.03491 - 0.01149 0.1593 0.05544 - 0.06629 - 0.00043<br />

I 1- 0.92) (1.35\ . (-I. 5S\ i<br />

: LANDQ 0.75417' 0.24510 0.3192" I O. III 051 1.51138" 0.00981-<br />

(3.0S)<br />

11.98) i<br />

13.391 •<br />

ASSET 0.00005" 0.00001 0.00002'" 1 0000006 0.00007S'" j 0.00000 I<br />

(1.97) 11.671 \ 11.731 i<br />

: IEOFA -0.02IS8' - 0.00724 - 0.0257' - 0.00895 - 0.00304 I - 0.00002<br />

\ (-5.19) (- 3.93) (-1.62)<br />

PIAGCA 0.00321' 0.00105 O. 0062'" 0.00214 0.00381 0.00002<br />

.12.05) ( 1.67) {1.61)<br />

i CASTE - 0.10025 - 0.03323 0.0873 0.03036 - 0.40360'" - 0.00262<br />

,<br />

_(- 0.77) {0.29) {-I.S2)<br />

I EDU 0.32436*** n 'An"l " CI


The result shows th<strong>at</strong> ASLH is neg<strong>at</strong>ive but not significant. This<br />

IS contradictory to the earlier findings th<strong>at</strong> larger the size of l<strong>and</strong><br />

owned by the household, gre<strong>at</strong>er is the probability of its access to the<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal sector (Kochar 1997 <strong>and</strong> Swain 2002). The neg<strong>at</strong>ive sign in our<br />

study might be <strong>at</strong>tributed to uncertainty of crop income owing to poor<br />

infrastructure facility in the study area. Importantly, the quality of<br />

l<strong>and</strong> (LANDQ) has a positive <strong>and</strong> significant effect on the access to<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal credit. It is quite interesting to note th<strong>at</strong> the marginal effect of<br />

l<strong>and</strong> quality increases the likelihood of access to credit by about 24<br />

per cent. This implies th<strong>at</strong> it is not the size of l<strong>and</strong>holding but the<br />

quality of l<strong>and</strong>, which m<strong>at</strong>ters <strong>for</strong> the bankers in the selection of a<br />

borrower, <strong>and</strong> in tum, increases the probability of farmers to access<br />

institutional credit. This variable behaves in the similar direction <strong>for</strong><br />

different sub-groups of farm households.<br />

On the issue of non-l<strong>and</strong> resources, the coefficient of ASSET is<br />

positive <strong>and</strong> significant <strong>at</strong> 5 per cent level, which implies th<strong>at</strong> larger<br />

the value of asset excluding l<strong>and</strong>, higher the probability of access to<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal credit. Ceteris Paribus, if the farmer is well equipped bv<br />

agricultural implements, there is a possibility of getting more income<br />

from farm activity, which, in tum, provides an indic<strong>at</strong>ion of his (or<br />

her) credit worthiness as a borrower. From this it is possible to infer<br />

th<strong>at</strong> peasant farmers who dispose of less valuable non-l<strong>and</strong> assets may<br />

have a correspondingly poor access to institutional credit. A farmer who<br />

is having higher non-farm income as a proportion to total income is<br />

less likely to have access to credit. This is evident from the fact th<strong>at</strong><br />

IEOFA coefficient is neg<strong>at</strong>ive <strong>and</strong> highly significant. This result<br />

indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> farmers with non-agricultural income may use it to<br />

meet their working capital requirements, <strong>and</strong> thus have no need to


approach a bank <strong>for</strong> a crop loan. Altern<strong>at</strong>ively, a bank may quite<br />

simply not have adequ<strong>at</strong>e in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion about the sources <strong>and</strong> amount<br />

of non-farm income to judge the creditworthiness of the borrower. This<br />

suggests th<strong>at</strong> bankers prefer tangible coll<strong>at</strong>eral (like l<strong>and</strong>, quality of<br />

l<strong>and</strong> or other assets) to select the borrower.<br />

A better irrig<strong>at</strong>ion facility also improves the farm household's<br />

prospects of obtaining a loan from the banks. This explan<strong>at</strong>ion is<br />

confirmed by the positive <strong>and</strong> highly significant coefficient of PIAGCA.<br />

However, the coefficient of this variable is positive but not significant<br />

<strong>at</strong> the conventional level of significance <strong>for</strong> medium <strong>and</strong> large size<br />

farmers. As expected, scheduled caste <strong>and</strong> scheduled tribe farmers are<br />

less likely to access <strong>for</strong>mal credit whereas this coefficient is<br />

surprisingly not significant except <strong>for</strong> the group of medium <strong>and</strong> large<br />

size farmers. However, educ<strong>at</strong>ion increases the probability of access<br />

to credit, i.e., higher the <strong>for</strong>mal educ<strong>at</strong>ion, higher is the probability of<br />

access to credit (this coefficient is being positive <strong>and</strong> significant <strong>at</strong> a<br />

10 per cent level). In this context, it can be argued th<strong>at</strong> educ<strong>at</strong>ional<br />

<strong>at</strong>tainment gives better in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion regarding the available banking<br />

facilities, <strong>and</strong> empowers the ability of farmers to approach a bank <strong>for</strong><br />

loan53. Nevertheless, this coefficient is neg<strong>at</strong>ive <strong>and</strong> not significant <strong>for</strong><br />

medium <strong>and</strong> large size farmers.<br />

Generally speaking, the results are quite in line with theoretical<br />

expect<strong>at</strong>ions <strong>and</strong> draw a plausible picture of the p<strong>at</strong>tern of farm<br />

household's credit access in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district. The highly significant<br />

chi-square <strong>and</strong> Pseudo R-square (33 per cent) clearly shows th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

51 It is evident from the marginal effect th<strong>at</strong> a one per cent increase in educ<strong>at</strong>ional<br />

<strong>at</strong>tainment increases the likelihood of access to credit by some 10 per cent.


estim<strong>at</strong>ed model is having good fit. The model points to a high degree<br />

of r<strong>at</strong>ioning by the <strong>for</strong>mal sector. Evalu<strong>at</strong>ing the probability of access<br />

<strong>at</strong> the mean <strong>levels</strong> of the explan<strong>at</strong>ory variables, 74 per cent of the<br />

households, belonging to all the c<strong>at</strong>egories are credit r<strong>at</strong>ioned by the<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal sector 54 .<br />

Determinants of Supply of Agricultural Credit<br />

Directed agricultural credit system assumes th<strong>at</strong> all farm households<br />

would have a positive dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal credit <strong>and</strong> it is a cheaper<br />

source <strong>for</strong> borrowing. It is further assumed th<strong>at</strong> both revealed <strong>and</strong><br />

potential dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit far exceeds the supply. On the basis of<br />

this assumption, many countries <strong>and</strong> financial institutions rely on<br />

supply-led approach to extend their credit facility. Irrespective of this<br />

approach, most theoretical <strong>and</strong> empirical studies argue th<strong>at</strong> dem<strong>and</strong><br />

far outweighs the supply of credit. This leads to a situ<strong>at</strong>ion where<br />

banks are compelled to adopt wide scale credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning.<br />

Credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning exists in two <strong>for</strong>ms, VIZ., price <strong>and</strong> non-price<br />

credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning. In the <strong>for</strong>mer case, the borrower is denied access to<br />

institutional credit regardless of whether or not he or she has fulfilled<br />

the stipul<strong>at</strong>ed terms <strong>and</strong> conditions. In the l<strong>at</strong>ter case, the farmer is<br />

able to borrow, but not as much as he or she wants or needs. The first<br />

type of credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning explains about vari<strong>at</strong>ions in the access to<br />

credit, i.e., wh<strong>at</strong> makes some farm households to access <strong>for</strong>mal credit<br />

<strong>and</strong> others not. The second type explains on vari<strong>at</strong>ions in the amount<br />

of credit flow from the <strong>for</strong>mal sector. Altern<strong>at</strong>ively, on wh<strong>at</strong> basis<br />

bankers determine the credit limit to the borrower? In our previous<br />

i; Based on similar assumptions as adopted in our model. Kochar (1997). <strong>and</strong> Swain<br />

12002) find th<strong>at</strong> 81 per cent <strong>and</strong> 71 per cent of the households in the respective<br />

studies were subject to credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning by the <strong>for</strong>mal sector.


model on access to credit (Probit Model), it was found th<strong>at</strong> the farm<br />

<strong>and</strong> household characteristics like quality of l<strong>and</strong>, value of non-l<strong>and</strong><br />

assets, the proportion of non-farm income, percentage of irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area<br />

to gross cropped area, <strong>and</strong> educ<strong>at</strong>ional qualific<strong>at</strong>ion of the borrower<br />

were the determining factors <strong>for</strong> accessing the <strong>for</strong>mal credit facility.<br />

The second model (OLS) in our household's level analysis<br />

specifies the factors th<strong>at</strong> determine the amount of credit given to the<br />

farmer borrower by the <strong>for</strong>mal sector. As was discussed, analysing<br />

the determinants of credit in terms of farmers who have received this<br />

is not a r<strong>and</strong>om selection of all the farmers in the popul<strong>at</strong>ion. Such a<br />

phenomenon leads to sample selection bias. In order to correct this<br />

problem of selectivity bias, Heckman two-step procedures have been<br />

used. In the first step, the Inverse Mills R<strong>at</strong>io (A) has been calcul<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

from the above Probit equ<strong>at</strong>ion, <strong>and</strong> in the second step this has been<br />

introduced as an additional explan<strong>at</strong>ory variable in the determinants<br />

of credit equ<strong>at</strong>ion. If the (/') variable is significant, the resultant<br />

equ<strong>at</strong>ion is unbiased (Heckman 1979). The second model, which deals<br />

with the amount of institutional credit lent, is set out in Table 6.7.<br />

The fact of credit flow - once access has been gained - can be<br />

looked <strong>at</strong> from two distinct viewpoints. From the supply side, the<br />

amount lent depends on the security offered <strong>and</strong> an assessment about<br />

the repayment capacity of the borrower. As noted, l<strong>and</strong> is an indic<strong>at</strong>or<br />

of the degree of security involved in the transaction, not least because<br />

in the eyes of a lender the higher the area under cultiv<strong>at</strong>ion the more<br />

likely it is th<strong>at</strong> the peasant farmer will gener<strong>at</strong>e sufficient output to<br />

repay the loan without difficulty. Given the self-<strong>finance</strong> capacity, the


oper<strong>at</strong>ed area 55 should be positively rel<strong>at</strong>ed to the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit,<br />

so the production surplus 56 can approxim<strong>at</strong>e most closely a capacity<br />

to repay. Because of the difficulty in calcul<strong>at</strong>ing the production<br />

surplus, the value of output by a farm household has been used to<br />

indic<strong>at</strong>e its creditworthiness. On the dem<strong>and</strong> side, the percentage of<br />

irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area to gross cropped area, expenditure on fertiliser <strong>and</strong><br />

pesticides, <strong>and</strong> the educ<strong>at</strong>ional qualific<strong>at</strong>ion of the borrower can all be<br />

expected to have a positive associ<strong>at</strong>ion with the flow of credit. Caste<br />

<strong>and</strong> the r<strong>at</strong>io of workers to family members, income excluding own<br />

farm activity can also influence the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit.<br />

Accordingly, it can be argued th<strong>at</strong> the actual flow of credit<br />

depends not only upon the factors governing the supply of credit but<br />

also on the factors influencing the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> it. Between different<br />

farm size-groups, disparities in the flow of credit can, there<strong>for</strong>e, be<br />

viewed in terms of the rel<strong>at</strong>ive strength of dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> supply factors.<br />

In the financial situ<strong>at</strong>ion characterised by the absence of credit<br />

r<strong>at</strong>ioning, the factors influencing the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit will obviously<br />

determine the quantum of credit supply. But in the financial system,<br />

where credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning (either price or non-price) exists, the factors<br />

55 Oper<strong>at</strong>ed area = L<strong>and</strong> owned + Leased in - Leased out. In the case of a financial<br />

system where <strong>for</strong>mal creditors insist on coll<strong>at</strong>eral (ownership rights of the l<strong>and</strong>),<br />

the credit extended to the farmer can assume to be neg<strong>at</strong>ively influenced under<br />

the tenancy system. Given the poor irrig<strong>at</strong>ion facility <strong>and</strong> uncertainty of crops,<br />

share tenancy contract oper<strong>at</strong>es in the study area. In this type of contract. the<br />

gross output is divided equally between the l<strong>and</strong>lord <strong>and</strong> tenant after deduction<br />

of cost of production. Generally, the l<strong>and</strong>owner only bears the cost of production<br />

<strong>and</strong> l<strong>at</strong>er, he takes it out in terms of output from total production. In this type of<br />

tenancy system the tenant only invests his labour <strong>for</strong>ce <strong>and</strong> not responsible <strong>for</strong><br />

all aspects of cultiv<strong>at</strong>ion. In our total sample, we had 15 cases like this. To avoid<br />

double counting we have not included the area under share tenancy in the<br />

oper<strong>at</strong>ed area of the tenant farmer.<br />

56 It can be defined as the difference between total income from production <strong>and</strong><br />

expenses incurred by the farm.


influencing the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit cannot be considered as ultim<strong>at</strong>e<br />

determinants of its supply. It is, there<strong>for</strong>e, necessary to investig<strong>at</strong>e<br />

whether the dem<strong>and</strong> or supply side factors account <strong>for</strong> the flow of<br />

credit, a question addressed in Table 6.7.<br />

Table 6.7: Definition, Measurement, Descriptive St<strong>at</strong>istics <strong>and</strong><br />

Expected Sign of Variables used in the OLS Equ<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

All Marginal I Medium<br />

Farmers <strong>and</strong> Small <strong>and</strong> Large<br />

Expected<br />

Variable Description Size Size<br />

,<br />

Sign<br />

Farmers Farmer~<br />

Mean Mean Mean i<br />

, Dep. Amount of Credit given 11,653.17 6,497 15,116 I<br />

I Var. * to the farmers (in (10,972.91) (4,166.62) (12,673.89) I<br />

Rupees) I<br />

I<br />

: PIAGCA Percentage of irrig<strong>at</strong>ed + ve 31.68<br />

34.6,<br />

272~ I<br />

, area to gross cropped (38.81) (36.50) (40.27) !<br />

area<br />

CASTE Caste st<strong>at</strong>us - ve 0.28 0040 0.19 '<br />

= I, if the borrower (0.45) (0049) (0.401 •<br />

belongs to SC or ST<br />

i ,<br />

= 0, otherwise ,<br />

,EDU Educ<strong>at</strong>ional + ve 0.29 0.11 0.40'<br />

qualific<strong>at</strong>ion of the (0.45) (0.32) (0.49)<br />

borrower<br />

= 1, <strong>for</strong> lOth <strong>and</strong> or<br />

above<br />

= 0, otherwise I<br />

'INEOFA Income excluding own + ve 17,789.54 7,696 24.5691<br />

farm activity (in Rupees) (31,660.67) (15,912.02) (37,343.80) .<br />

WFM Workers to family - ve 0.43 0.49 0.39.<br />

members (r<strong>at</strong>io) (0.17) (0.18) (0.15)<br />

- 01\ Oper<strong>at</strong>ed areas (in + ve 8.02 3.88 10.81<br />

Acres) (6.65) (1.74) (7.26) 1<br />

c<br />

i<br />

:EXPFP Expenditure on fertiliser + ve 7,188.20 3,211 9,859<br />

I <strong>and</strong> pesticides (in (7,432.64) (2,268.92) (8,453.03<br />

L Rupees)<br />

,VAO Value of farm output + ve 43,947.21 16,767 62.202 I<br />

, produced in the year (43,309.81 ) (11,696.71) (47.132.37) i<br />

. (in Rupees)<br />

I~IR Inverse Mills R<strong>at</strong>io (I,) 0.4594 0.6411 0.2339 '<br />

~\umber of Observ<strong>at</strong>ions 112 45 67<br />

\ote: Figures m parenthesIs mdlc<strong>at</strong>e St<strong>and</strong>ard DeVi<strong>at</strong>IOn<br />

-


As we expected, most of the parameters have the expected sign<br />

<strong>and</strong> are significant (Table 6.8). The coefficient of PIAGCA is positive<br />

<strong>and</strong> highly significant, which implies th<strong>at</strong> a unit (one per cent)<br />

increases in proportion of irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area to gross cropped area, OIl an<br />

average, leads to an increase of 47.55 rupees (0.1292 per cent) in the<br />

amount of credit (<strong>for</strong> the entire sample). This variable also behaves in<br />

similar direction to marginal <strong>and</strong> small, <strong>and</strong> medium <strong>and</strong> large group<br />

of farmers. This is true <strong>and</strong> in con<strong>for</strong>mity with earlier studies th<strong>at</strong><br />

irrig<strong>at</strong>ion facility is an important factor to determine the amount of<br />

credit disbursed by the <strong>for</strong>mal lender. Non-Scheduled Caste <strong>and</strong><br />

Scheduled Tribe farmers enjoy more credit compared to Scheduled<br />

Caste <strong>and</strong> Scheduled Tribe (SC/ST) farmers. This reflects in the<br />

neg<strong>at</strong>ive <strong>and</strong> slgmticant coefficient of the variable CASTE. The positive<br />

<strong>and</strong> significant coefficient of human capital variable (EDU) clearly<br />

shows th<strong>at</strong> the farmers who has possessed a 10th st<strong>and</strong>ard level of<br />

educ<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> above have obtained more credit compared to their less<br />

educ<strong>at</strong>ed counterparts.<br />

Not surprising is the link between expenditure on fertiliser <strong>and</strong><br />

pesticides, on the one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> the lender provision <strong>for</strong> more credit,<br />

on the other. Fieldwork in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district confirms th<strong>at</strong> the per<br />

acre expenditure by large <strong>and</strong> medium sized farmers on these inputs<br />

was very high. This, in turn, not only raised agricultural productivity<br />

but also enhanced their creditworthiness. Each one per cent increase<br />

in EXPFP lead, on an average, to a 0.5329 per cent increase in the<br />

amount of credit (<strong>for</strong> the total sample).


Table 6.8: Determinants of Formal Credit: Selectivity<br />

Corrected OLS Result<br />

(Dependent Variable = Amount of Credit given to Farmers (in Rupees))<br />

c----.. ----.<br />

Coefficients<br />

- - ---- -----<br />

-- 1<br />

- --- .<br />

Variables All Farmers Marginal <strong>and</strong> Small . Medium <strong>and</strong> Large<br />

i<br />

Size Farmers I Size Farmers ,<br />

--- - c;-;I<br />

! Constant 1.844.540 3.578. 14 '" ) 683.31.<br />

,<br />

(0.701 (1. 80) (0. IILl<br />

PIAGCA 47. 548 ' O. 22 *** 74. 15' .<br />

(2.631 -


176<br />

per cent. The neg<strong>at</strong>ive <strong>and</strong> significant coefficient of OA <strong>for</strong> marginal<br />

<strong>and</strong> small farmers indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> even if OA increased, it lead to less<br />

supply of credit. This can be explained by the fact th<strong>at</strong> the OA of most<br />

of the small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers included l<strong>and</strong> leased in also. In the<br />

case of the financial system, where <strong>for</strong>mal creditors insisted on<br />

coll<strong>at</strong>eral (ownership rights of l<strong>and</strong>), credit extended to the farmer<br />

would, there<strong>for</strong>e, be neg<strong>at</strong>ively influenced under the tenancy system S7 .<br />

The coefficient of worker to household members (WFM) was positive<br />

<strong>and</strong> significant <strong>for</strong> marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers. This indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong><br />

increase in WFM could lead to the supply of more credit. Bankers<br />

might have perceived th<strong>at</strong> the increase in the number of working<br />

members could provide more income through wage or any other<br />

economic activity (either farm or non-farm). Probably, this might<br />

enhance their creditworthiness. This argument can also be supported<br />

by the positive <strong>and</strong> significant coefficient of INEOFA <strong>for</strong> marginal <strong>and</strong><br />

small farmers.<br />

The result shows th<strong>at</strong> the Inverse Mills R<strong>at</strong>io (A) was positive<br />

(neg<strong>at</strong>ive <strong>for</strong> marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers) <strong>and</strong> significant <strong>and</strong> the<br />

resultant equ<strong>at</strong>ion was unbiased. The R-square values were 0.69, 0.71<br />

<strong>and</strong> 0.66 <strong>for</strong> the estim<strong>at</strong>ed equ<strong>at</strong>ion of all sample farmers, marginal<br />

<strong>and</strong> small, <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> medium <strong>and</strong> large size, respectively. This shows<br />

th<strong>at</strong> 69 per cent, 71 per cent, <strong>and</strong> 66 per cent of the vari<strong>at</strong>ions in the<br />

amount of credit obtained by all farmers, marginal <strong>and</strong> small, <strong>and</strong><br />

medium <strong>and</strong> large farmers, respectively have been explained by the<br />

included variables in these models. Further, the whole significance of<br />

" Out of 45 marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers who had obtained loan from the <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

banking system, 42 per cent of them were cultiv<strong>at</strong>ing through fixed tenancy<br />

system.


the model was also highly significant <strong>at</strong> 1 per cent level, which<br />

rejected the hypothesis th<strong>at</strong> all the slope parameters are zero.<br />

Table 6.9: Determinants of Formal Credit: Tobit Results<br />

(Dependent Variable = Amount of Credit given to the Farmers (in RupeesJ]<br />

All Farmers Marginal <strong>and</strong> Small Medium <strong>and</strong> Large<br />

Variables Size Farmers Size Farmers<br />

Coefficient Marginal Coefficient Marginal Coefficient Marginal<br />

Effect Effect Effect<br />

Constant - 1,305.28 - 816.78 -5,319.94 -2,312.98 1,048.86 904.74<br />

PIAGCA 68.63' 42.94 25.14 ... 10.93 79.99 .. 69.00<br />

(3.40) (I.61l (2.25\<br />

CASTE -3,874.82" -2,424.67 -1,110.96 ,.. -483.02 - 6,936.21 ' -<br />

1- 2.50\ (-1.66) (-2.40) 5,983.17<br />

EDU 2,341.17 1,464.98 1,370.24 , •• 595.74 1,743.42 ,., 1,503.87<br />

(1.25\ (1.781 (1.64)<br />

INEOFA -0.001 - 0.007 -0.02 -001 0.01 0.01<br />

(- 0.04) (·0.641 (0.33)<br />

WFM -5,819.59 -3,641.60 1,359.97 , •• 591.28 - 4,891.05 -4,219.02<br />

1- 1.381 '1.84~ f- O.62i<br />

lOA 15.53 9.72 -327.73 -142.49 - 90.03 -77.66<br />

,<br />

(0.05) (-0. 63) (- 0.22\<br />

IEXPFP 0.87 • 0.55 2.16 • 0.94 0.75 ., 0.65<br />

12.99\ (4.321 (2.01)<br />

iVAO 0.062'" 0.04 0.13 ." 0.05 0.06 *** 0.05<br />

(1.61) /1.73) (1.83)<br />

'Sigma 8,659.41' 4,335.96 • 10,052.59 •<br />

,<br />

(14.28) (8.68) 111.13)<br />

, Log· -1,224.72 - 470.52 - 727.80<br />

I likelihood<br />

. R - squared 0.63 0.65 0.62<br />

I. Number of 200 117 83<br />

observ<strong>at</strong>ions<br />

Note: 1) FIgures In parentheses mdlc<strong>at</strong>e (-values<br />

2) '1% level significance; "5% level significance, '''10 % level<br />

3) Marginal Effect - Partial deriv<strong>at</strong>ive of expected value with respect to vector of<br />

characteristics. They are computed <strong>at</strong> the means of the explan<strong>at</strong>ory<br />

variables.<br />

The ordinary least square regression is inappropri<strong>at</strong>e when the<br />

dependent variable is discontinuous (Pindyck <strong>and</strong> Rubinfield 1997).<br />

Logit <strong>and</strong> Pro bit models are appropri<strong>at</strong>e when the dependent variable<br />

is discrete, usually taking two values, 0 or 1. These models are useful<br />

if the question is whether or not farmers have access to credit, but are<br />

mappropri<strong>at</strong>e when it is important to measure the amount of credit<br />

177


obtained. The Tobit Model h<strong>and</strong>les censored dependent variables<br />

(continuous between some lower <strong>and</strong> possibly upper bound) better<br />

<strong>and</strong>, hence, is superior to Logit <strong>and</strong> Probit (Pindyck <strong>and</strong> Rubinfield<br />

1997). The Tobit model has been, there<strong>for</strong>e, used <strong>and</strong> the results are<br />

presented in Table 6.9. The sign <strong>and</strong> significance level of the<br />

coefficients are almost the same as those discussed in the OLS model,<br />

except in the case of coefficients of lNEOFA <strong>and</strong> OA. The educ<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

variable is significant in OLS <strong>for</strong> all the three cases, whereas in Tobit<br />

equ<strong>at</strong>ion it is significant only in the case of marginal <strong>and</strong> small, <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>for</strong> the group of medium <strong>and</strong> large size farmers. The Tobit results<br />

again confirm th<strong>at</strong> PIAGCA, VA~, EXPFP, CASTE are important<br />

variables in determining the amount of credit obtained. Further, the<br />

co-efficient of Sigma is highly significant <strong>at</strong> 1 per cent level, which<br />

confirms th<strong>at</strong> the results are unbiased.<br />

Conclusions<br />

The p<strong>at</strong>tern of <strong>for</strong>mal credit flow <strong>at</strong> farm <strong>levels</strong> shows th<strong>at</strong> the credit<br />

r<strong>at</strong>ioning goes in favour of large farm households, <strong>and</strong> the obtained<br />

amount is inadequ<strong>at</strong>e to meet their production expenditure <strong>for</strong> most of<br />

the farmer borrowers who had obtained credit. Since there is<br />

inadequ<strong>at</strong>e availability of <strong>for</strong>mal credit, the farmers tend to depend<br />

more on in<strong>for</strong>mal sector. It is clear th<strong>at</strong> fonnal lenders are not in a<br />

position to replace infonnal lenders to provide credit to agricultural<br />

borrowers, even with a widespread network of fonnal financial<br />

institutions, <strong>and</strong> the suggested measures by Gupta Committee aiming<br />

<strong>at</strong> improved quality of credit delivery system.<br />

The results on the determinants of access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit<br />

suggest th<strong>at</strong> several factors were inhibiting agricultural borrowers <strong>and</strong><br />

178


especially the marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers from obtaining production<br />

credit, despite the presence of number of <strong>for</strong>mal credit institutions in<br />

the study area. Apparently, the mere existence of <strong>for</strong>mal credit<br />

institutions does not guarantee th<strong>at</strong> marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers will<br />

benefit from them s8 . Thus, mere loc<strong>at</strong>ion of a bank branch in a village<br />

without restructuring its management to make it more broad-based<br />

with proper represent<strong>at</strong>ion of agricultural borrowers belonging to<br />

either lower castes or illiter<strong>at</strong>e or both (as noted by Sen, 1975;<br />

Gh<strong>at</strong>ak, 1977, 1983; Sarap, 1990) is not enough to ensure effective<br />

access of <strong>for</strong>mal credit to the rural borrowers.<br />

The farm, <strong>and</strong> household characteristics such as quality of l<strong>and</strong>,<br />

value of assets excludmg l<strong>and</strong>, irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area, <strong>and</strong> educ<strong>at</strong>ional<br />

qualific<strong>at</strong>ion of the borrower determined the access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit. It<br />

is quite interesting to note th<strong>at</strong> the quality of l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> value of output<br />

are found to be significant in determining the access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit<br />

<strong>and</strong> the amount obtained respectively, r<strong>at</strong>her than the size of<br />

l<strong>and</strong>holding. It seems th<strong>at</strong> bankers are giving preference to the safer<br />

borrower <strong>and</strong> leaving marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers to the unorganised<br />

credit market. The above determinants of access to credit indic<strong>at</strong>e the<br />

creditworthiness of the agricultural borrowers. Thus, it is the bankers'<br />

assessment on the creditworthiness th<strong>at</strong> decides whether or not a<br />

farm household should have access to credit:. The factors like area<br />

under irrig<strong>at</strong>ion, value of agricultural output, expenditure on inputs<br />

(fertiliser <strong>and</strong> pesticides), caste <strong>and</strong> educ<strong>at</strong>ional qualific<strong>at</strong>ion of the<br />

borrower are the important variables th<strong>at</strong> determine the amount of<br />

credit obtained. On the whole, one can argue th<strong>at</strong> the asset-based<br />

" This finding also corrobor<strong>at</strong>es with Sarap's study in 1990. where field<br />

investig<strong>at</strong>ion was conducted during the year 1981-2 in six villages of Sambalpur<br />

district of Orissa st<strong>at</strong>e in India.<br />

179


lending policies coupled with the bankers' assessments on<br />

creditworthiness determines both access to credit <strong>and</strong> amount of<br />

credit obtained by the farmer borrowers.<br />

The estim<strong>at</strong>es also suggest a rel<strong>at</strong>ively high dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit<br />

with fairly widespread credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district. This<br />

requires further development of credit programmes to support the<br />

credit requirement of different c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers, <strong>and</strong> especially<br />

those belonging to marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmer c<strong>at</strong>egories.<br />

In the econometric specific<strong>at</strong>ion, we assume th<strong>at</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

borrowing is determined by bank decision on access to credit <strong>and</strong> has<br />

been estim<strong>at</strong>ed by using univari<strong>at</strong>e pro bit model. However, one can<br />

also generalise (a) where the probability of borrowing from the <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

sector is jointly determined by the bank decision on access as well as<br />

the farm household's dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> loans, <strong>and</strong> (b) where the households<br />

may have zero dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal credit <strong>and</strong> they are free to choose<br />

between in<strong>for</strong>mal <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal sector. This generalis<strong>at</strong>ion can be<br />

estim<strong>at</strong>ed using bivari<strong>at</strong>e Probit <strong>and</strong> Multinomial Legit model.<br />

Clearly, there is a need <strong>for</strong> further research <strong>and</strong> subsequent <strong>at</strong>tempts<br />

in this direction, which will hopefully allow us to explore these<br />

al tern<strong>at</strong>ives, in detail.


Chapter 7<br />

CREDIT DELIVERY SYSTEM, CREDIT-GAP AND COPING<br />

STRATEGY OF AGRICULTURAL BORROWERS<br />

Introduction<br />

An analysis of the determinants of access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit in our<br />

previous chapter showed th<strong>at</strong> several factors were inhibiting<br />

agricultural borrowers, in general, <strong>and</strong> marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers, in<br />

particular, from obtaining production credit. The poor quality of l<strong>and</strong>,<br />

illiteracy <strong>and</strong> lower caste st<strong>at</strong>us had an adverse effect on the access of<br />

agricultural borrowers to <strong>for</strong>mal credit institutions. It is also found<br />

th<strong>at</strong> small proportions of the total number of farmers in rural areas<br />

were accessing credit from financial institutions, <strong>and</strong> out of th<strong>at</strong> a<br />

small group grabbed a large share of the net volume of credit<br />

disbursed. Importantly, the credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning goes in favour of large<br />

farmers. It is also reported by most of the farmers from the study area<br />

th<strong>at</strong> the amount obtained as loan was inadequ<strong>at</strong>e to meet their<br />

production costs. Furthermore, some of the farmer borrowers st<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

th<strong>at</strong> they had one or other problems while obtaining credit from<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal financial institutions. Some of these problems also contributed<br />

to the higher transaction costs <strong>and</strong> delay in the disbursement of<br />

credit.<br />

In this context, one can raise the following questions. Who are<br />

these agricultural borrowers who face problems in accessing <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

credit facility? Are these problems the same across various size of<br />

l<strong>and</strong>holdings? Which class of farmers face higher transaction costs<br />

while obtaining <strong>for</strong>mal loans? Since the obtained loan amount from<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal sources is inadequ<strong>at</strong>e, wh<strong>at</strong> is the magnitude of the credit-gap<br />

181


among farm households? Given the self-<strong>finance</strong> capacity, wh<strong>at</strong> is the<br />

coping str<strong>at</strong>egy of the farmers to meet their cost of cultiv<strong>at</strong>ion? To<br />

answer these questions both qualit<strong>at</strong>ive <strong>and</strong> quantit<strong>at</strong>ive d<strong>at</strong>a were<br />

collected from 200 r<strong>and</strong>omly selected borrowers from the service area<br />

of four different bank branches59.<br />

Credit Delivery System<br />

It is argued th<strong>at</strong> the disturbing trends in the rural credit delivery<br />

system can be <strong>at</strong>tributed to the poor quality of lending (Rajasekhar<br />

<strong>and</strong> Vyasulu 1990). The supply-led approach with poor quality of<br />

lending failed to provide the credit requirement of agricultural<br />

borrowers, on the one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> made agricultural lending<br />

un _ .• D.rn.fi.1t:::!h.1p, .. _ ___ _


Table 7.1 shows th<strong>at</strong> a majority of the borrowers had one or<br />

more problems on the credit delivery system. Such problems could be<br />

grouped broadly under two c<strong>at</strong>egories, viz., during <strong>and</strong> after obtaining<br />

loans. Problems in obtaining loans included complic<strong>at</strong>ed procedures,<br />

lack of previous experience, distant loc<strong>at</strong>ion of the bank, <strong>and</strong> bribe. As<br />

many as 56.5 per cent of the agricultural borrowers st<strong>at</strong>ed th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

bank procedures were complex. They faced serious problems in<br />

getting No Dues Certific<strong>at</strong>e (NDC) from the local financial institution.<br />

This seemed to be a widespread problem in the area where Cooper<strong>at</strong>ives,<br />

RRBs <strong>and</strong> Commercial Banks were working. As per the<br />

recommend<strong>at</strong>ion, importance should have been given to the credit<br />

st<strong>at</strong>us of the borrower r<strong>at</strong>her than to no dues certific<strong>at</strong>e, but still the<br />

borrowers were required to submit NDC while taking loans. The<br />

imposition of this requirement took more time <strong>and</strong> also posed problem<br />

to few borrowers. In spite of rapid expansion of the bank branches,<br />

since most of the borrowers (56 per cent) did not have previous<br />

experience of borrowing from the <strong>for</strong>mal sector, it aggrav<strong>at</strong>ed the<br />

situ<strong>at</strong>ion. Some of the borrowers especially those who wanted loan <strong>for</strong><br />

the purpose of allied activities st<strong>at</strong>ed th<strong>at</strong> the bank officials were<br />

indifferent to them. A general view among the borrowers of this kind<br />

was th<strong>at</strong> "unless one bribes the bank officials" they would not sanction<br />

the loan. Based on the in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion, it is found th<strong>at</strong> 24 per cent of the<br />

borrowers gave bribe to the bank officials to get the loan. On the<br />

whole, most of them felt th<strong>at</strong> "it is better to obtain a loan from<br />

moneylender than to approach the bank 61 ".<br />

" Rajasekhar <strong>and</strong> Vyasulu (1990) also found a similar problem in their study 111 Pali<br />

district of Rajasthan.


Table 7.1: Problems Faced by the Farmer Borrowers in<br />

Obtaining Loans<br />

~ ~~~ _~ .. Proi>f~II1s-~-__ Y'es-lPe~cent= lio=-~Percel1t-:-::TotaJ ,<br />

I_~"~ .--~ -~-. Be<strong>for</strong>e Obtllinin.KLoan (~ i<br />

Coml'lic~te.dProcedure 113[ 56:-5'_87 -=-_43:--5:~- 2QO<br />

No P~e\lious_Experience 11~_~~_Q..~88 4±o.O ___ 200<br />

.[)i~tant Loc<strong>at</strong>ion of the Bankl 961 48. 01 1041 52.0 2001<br />

]Bribe ~ 4t3\._~4~1 152;76.01'-- 200\<br />

I=:-:-::-:-:--;~_~ __ ~A",f",te",r"--O~btaining!-oan lB.,.),---c-c_~_~<br />

[nac:l"8.ua.'-ite-,:,:Loc::an=~_~_--jI~--",-1~39",i,--~6~9;O-"c'5;:.;i~-:-.6;!-:1~i~_30. ~_. __ ~_200<br />

~IU~n~t~im~e~1~y~Lo~a~n~~ ____ ~I_,--9~8~\_~4~9~.~O~i~~1~0~2~1_~~51.0~_200J<br />

Source: Field Survey<br />

The agricultural borrowers also st<strong>at</strong>ed th<strong>at</strong>, the loan amounts<br />

were inadequ<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> untimely. About 69.5 per cent of the agricultural<br />

borrower out of the total sample felt th<strong>at</strong> the disbursed loan amount<br />

was inadequ<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> 49 per cent were of the view th<strong>at</strong> it was not<br />

available <strong>at</strong> the needed hour.<br />

Based on these findings one of the important questions th<strong>at</strong><br />

could be asked was who were these agricultural borrowers who faced<br />

problems in accessing <strong>for</strong>mal credit facility? Table 7.2 explains th<strong>at</strong><br />

these problems were uneven across different size of l<strong>and</strong>holdings.<br />

Importantly, most of these problems were rel<strong>at</strong>ed to marginal <strong>and</strong><br />

small farmers. Out of total sample about 80 per cent of the farmer<br />

borrowers, who belonged to marginal <strong>and</strong> small c<strong>at</strong>egories found th<strong>at</strong><br />

the <strong>for</strong>mal banking system was complic<strong>at</strong>ed. These c<strong>at</strong>egories of<br />

borrowers also narr<strong>at</strong>ed their poor experience with the institutional<br />

credit system. This indic<strong>at</strong>es how far our banking system is good<br />

enough in covering these borrowers. Bribing to the bank officials<br />

seems to be a widespread problem in the case of marginal c<strong>at</strong>egory<br />

farmers. A general feeling among the borrowers was th<strong>at</strong> « bribing is<br />

tile only means to obtain a loan <strong>for</strong> allied agricultural activities under<br />

the subsidy <strong>and</strong> or poverty allevi<strong>at</strong>ion schemes". The evidence shows


th<strong>at</strong> the creditworthiness, viability of the proposal, <strong>and</strong> the amount of<br />

cash disbursed were positively rel<strong>at</strong>ed with the amount of bribe, while<br />

the time taken to get the loan sanctioned was neg<strong>at</strong>ively rel<strong>at</strong>ed62.<br />

Table 7.2: Size Class of L<strong>and</strong>holding-wise Frequency<br />

Distribution of Problems Faced by the Farmer Borrowers<br />

~-T 0.01=-2:5012.51:5.00 -5:01-10_00 10_01 acres·<br />

Problems I Acr~s I Acres I Acres ,<strong>and</strong> Above. Total<br />

i-_________ -LtMarglll.o!lJ... JSmallJ _--' l.Med.iuml.....:.--..JLargeJ __'__ ___ .<br />

Be<strong>for</strong>e Obtaining Loan<br />

",C",o"m=plli",ca"-:t",eo-d=Pr-'.o"-,c""e"-d""u...,re,---+-----,,5,,,9...l(,,,!52,.,.-'".2i":4--'3,,,1,--(:\2~",-i~ 16 ! 14jf-7-(6:2j 113 (fOOL<br />

~I N"'o~P.!.r~ev"i~ou"'s~E~xp""'e""r-'.;'ie=:'::n":.ce~-+-----"5'-'c7--'!~!50~.~9J.!.1111....:3"-'.1 (27.7). 19 (17.QL__ 5...14 5Lil 2 (1"00)<br />

Distant Loc<strong>at</strong>ion of the 31 (32.3)1 31 (32.3)'1 23 (24.0) II (11.5) 96 (100)<br />

@ank i 1<br />

~B"",ri",b",-e _______..L-....:4,,,"--,2(But._3 (6~ 2""'(4"'"".2L ::-J._-=---_-----cl;-~c .:n: -'-::48(100)<br />

~~~~~~~----,-~Aft~e~r~O~b~ta~in~i~n~L~o~a~n~~~~_,~~~~ ___ _<br />

'lnade u<strong>at</strong>e Loan 41 29.5 34 24.5): 4l.i29.~ ___ 2:3.(16.~.139 (100)<br />

Untimely Loan 58 59.2: 19 19.4 16 16.3), 5~,ll_98(!OOl<br />

Note: Figures in pAre.nthe.~i~Lare_percentages of f3rm hou~ehold~ in each c<strong>at</strong>egory<br />

who have faced problems in obtaining agricultural loans.<br />

Source: Field Survey<br />

Bribing takes place in many <strong>for</strong>ms starting from the project<br />

initi<strong>at</strong>ion to sanction_ Even in the case of no direct bribing, the<br />

bankers manipul<strong>at</strong>e while buying the loan assets_ Hence, the above<br />

practice contradicts the recommend<strong>at</strong>ion made by the Gupta<br />

committee, which has preferred distribution of loan amount in cash.<br />

In this aspect, two important dimensions were derived from the<br />

discussion with the bankers <strong>and</strong> beneficiaries in the field areas. The<br />

"' Chaudhuri (1993) has gone into an indirect analysis of the effects of bribing on<br />

the delay in the disbursement of <strong>for</strong>mal credit. In a sample of 75 farmers from the<br />

two villages, 57 per cent of the fanners emphasised th<strong>at</strong> the delay in getting<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal credit could be reduced by increasing the bribe <strong>and</strong> the remaining 43 per<br />

cent did not respond. However, he mentioned th<strong>at</strong> a st<strong>at</strong>istical correl<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

analysis between the delay <strong>and</strong> the bribing r<strong>at</strong>e could not be done because the<br />

d<strong>at</strong>a on the l<strong>at</strong>ter could not be obtained from all the agricultural borrowers who<br />

had given bribe.<br />

There is empirical evidence <strong>for</strong> the delay in disbursing <strong>for</strong>mal credit. The dela)' is<br />

controlled by an official of the <strong>for</strong>mal credit agency, <strong>and</strong> it can be reduced by the<br />

farmer bribing the official (Chaudhuri <strong>and</strong> Gupta, 1996). In their theoretical<br />

model they found th<strong>at</strong>, in eqUilibrium. the official either would not take a bribe or<br />

would choose a bribing r<strong>at</strong>e such th<strong>at</strong> the effective interest r<strong>at</strong>e on <strong>for</strong>mal credit<br />

(incorpor<strong>at</strong>ing the bribe) would be equal to the interest r<strong>at</strong>e on in<strong>for</strong>mal credit.


ankers were of the view th<strong>at</strong> the probability of misuse of loans by the<br />

beneficiary was more in the case, where loans were disbursed in cash.<br />

They also argued th<strong>at</strong> in the case of misuse of loans, bank looses<br />

partially or completely the hypothec<strong>at</strong>ed loan asset th<strong>at</strong> work as<br />

coll<strong>at</strong>eral <strong>for</strong> the bank till the loan was repaid. However, the borrowers<br />

argued th<strong>at</strong> the kind components lead to distortion since their choice<br />

was restricted. In most of the cases, the bankers got the loan asset<br />

without considering the quality, <strong>and</strong> technical viability of the project<br />

with the given environment. The beneficiaries were of the opinion th<strong>at</strong><br />

this kind of problem was prominent in the case of small business,<br />

diary-firm, go<strong>at</strong> rearing, sheep rearing <strong>and</strong> so on. In this process, in<br />

order to disburse the loan amount in terms of cash, both the bank<br />

officials <strong>and</strong> beneficiaries got into bargaining. Bargaining between the<br />

lender <strong>and</strong> borrower brought the joint product called "bribe" by<br />

neglecting the very objective of the scheme <strong>and</strong> the concerned project.<br />

Th<strong>at</strong> obtaining a loan was a complic<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>and</strong> lengthy process<br />

was also evident from Table 7.3. About 60 per cent of the loans took<br />

more than two to eight months to get sanctioned in the case of<br />

marginal farmers 63 . It is observed th<strong>at</strong> the time taken <strong>for</strong> obtaining<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal short-term loan was inversely rel<strong>at</strong>ed to the size of l<strong>and</strong>holding.<br />

This finding also collabor<strong>at</strong>ed with the earlier study made by<br />

Rajasekhar <strong>and</strong> Vyasulu (1990). There is empirical evidence of delay<br />

in disbursing <strong>for</strong>mal credit. Sarap (1990) has found th<strong>at</strong> small <strong>and</strong><br />

marginal farmers also face substantial delay in getting <strong>for</strong>mal (shortterm)<br />

credit. The empirical analysis of Chaudhuri (1993), in the case<br />

of two selected villages of West Bengal pointed out th<strong>at</strong> farmers with<br />

OJ<br />

Around 80 per cent of these loans were <strong>for</strong> aUied agricultural activities. The<br />

disbursement ofiong term loans is more time consuming (see, George et aI1985).


less than 1.5 acres of l<strong>and</strong>holdings had to wait <strong>for</strong> nearly eight weeks<br />

to get loans from the d<strong>at</strong>e of applic<strong>at</strong>ion. This problem has also been<br />

observed by Bedbak (1986) who made a survey of a village of Sonepur<br />

subdivision of Orissa.<br />

Table 7.3: Time ~ent to get the Loan Sanctioned<br />

-- S~eClassof the --c Numb~_ ~r::.Da'y,! _ ~.en_tlo (iet .the LEan_Sanctioned _<br />

L<strong>and</strong>holdings (in Acres), 0 - 15. 15 - 30 30 - 60 , 60 <strong>and</strong> Above Total Farmers<br />

r~~~ Y~~I-~:I ~:~---6H+:::'--:g[ ~~b}<br />

5.01-10.00 42.6, 51. I, 4.3 .1.o..l.. __ }Oo.. (47)<br />

10.01 <strong>and</strong> Above 63. 9; 30. 6, 2.~ 2.81----__ 100.. [361.<br />

,All Classes 29. 51 4l. 5\ 6 . .Qt.. ___ 2LQ' __ 100 J200)<br />

Note: Figures in parentheses indic<strong>at</strong>e the number of farmers.<br />

Source: Field Survey<br />

The other important aspect of the <strong>for</strong>mal credit delivery system<br />

was lh<strong>at</strong> the obtained ioan amounts were inadequ<strong>at</strong>e. We have<br />

obtained in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion on amount dem<strong>and</strong>ed <strong>and</strong> the amount<br />

sanctioned (short-term loans). The shortage of <strong>for</strong>mal credit was<br />

assumed to be the differential amount between loan dem<strong>and</strong>ed <strong>and</strong><br />

sanctioned. The distribution of loans on the basis of percentage of<br />

amount shortage 64 to amount sanctioned is presented in Table 7.4. It<br />

is observed th<strong>at</strong> the amount sanctioned was less than the amount<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>ed in the case of a majority of the farmers. However, only 44.8<br />

per cent of the large size farmers obtained the loan amount of wh<strong>at</strong><br />

they had asked <strong>for</strong>. In the case of other c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers the<br />

amount sanctioned was well short of amount required. This suggests<br />

th<strong>at</strong> irrespective of the l<strong>and</strong>holdings, the sanctioned loan amounts<br />

were generally inadequ<strong>at</strong>e in the study area. It is also corrobor<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

with the finding of Table 7.1 wherein as many as 69.5 per cent of the<br />

"' The shortage amount is a proxy <strong>for</strong> the inadequ<strong>at</strong>e availability of <strong>for</strong>mal credit,<br />

<strong>and</strong> may not be tre<strong>at</strong>ed as the credit-gap. This is due to the fact th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

calcul<strong>at</strong>ion of credit-gap may not represent the shortage amount without<br />

considering his cost of production <strong>and</strong> self-<strong>finance</strong> capacity. The issue of creditgap<br />

has been discussed in the subsequent section.


farmer borrowers st<strong>at</strong>ed th<strong>at</strong> the loan amounts were inadequ<strong>at</strong>e In<br />

n<strong>at</strong>ure.<br />

Table 7.4: Shortage of Amount Sanctioned to Amount<br />

Dem<strong>and</strong>ed<br />

,- SiZe-Class ofth·e--,.---------P-e;centa-geofShortage---------- -<br />

,L<strong>and</strong>holdingsJin Acres) I 0% 1 - 25% I 26-=--50%~-AbOve 50% - Total No. of Farmers<br />

!0.()1-2.50 46. 2 23. II 15.41- --154--=--~_ 100- (13)<br />

2.51-5.00 ; 31. 3 34.4: 28. 11 6. 3<br />

10-"----1321<br />

'5.01-10.00 10. 5 47. 4 21. Ii 21 1<br />

100 P8L<br />

110.01 <strong>and</strong> Above 44. 8 13.8 3101 10.3'<br />

100 (29}<br />

All classes 29. 5 32. I 25.0, 13. 4<br />

100 (l12}<br />

Note. Figures m parenthesIs mdlc<strong>at</strong>e the number of farmers.<br />

Source: Field Survey<br />

This shows th<strong>at</strong> the <strong>for</strong>mal credit delivery system in the study<br />

area was poor in qUality. It was neither adequ<strong>at</strong>e nor timely <strong>for</strong> most<br />

of the agricultural borrowers. Thus, based on this in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion it could<br />

be concluded th<strong>at</strong> the Gupta Committee recommend<strong>at</strong>ions had hardly<br />

improved the quality of credit delivery system in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district of<br />

Orissa. The poor quality of credit delivery system, along with some<br />

other factors might have contributed to higher transaction costs. This<br />

is further discussed below.<br />

Borrowing Costs <strong>for</strong> Agricultural Credit<br />

The effective price from the borrowers' point of view was the real cost<br />

including interest payment <strong>and</strong> other transaction costs. To obtain a<br />

loan the farmer had to s<strong>at</strong>isfy certain terms <strong>and</strong> conditions th<strong>at</strong> were<br />

required by the lenders' credit delivery system, which resulted in the<br />

borrower transaction costs. The borrower transaction costs in the<br />

study included applic<strong>at</strong>ion fees, service fees, document<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong><br />

paper works, bribe to officer/ technician/ bank staff/ leader or<br />

middleman <strong>for</strong> negoti<strong>at</strong>ion, travel expenses incurred by the borrower,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the opportunity cost of the borrower's time spent to obtain the<br />

loan.


In the study area, it is found th<strong>at</strong> many small <strong>and</strong> new<br />

borrowers were required to visit the financial institutions <strong>at</strong> least five<br />

to six times to maintain <strong>for</strong>mality, withdraw a portion of the loan <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>for</strong> repayment. The cost of time has become one of the important<br />

aspects of borrowing costs, particularly when transactions are<br />

contracted during the planting, weeding or harvesting seasons when<br />

the opportunity costs of the borrower's time is high (Sarap 1990;<br />

Adams <strong>and</strong> Vogel 1986; Adams <strong>and</strong> Nehman 1979). To avoid the<br />

complexity of calcul<strong>at</strong>ing the time cost of one day, it has been<br />

considered as equivalent to one day of wage labour <strong>and</strong> calcul<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>at</strong><br />

the wage r<strong>at</strong>e prevailing during the process of acquisition <strong>and</strong><br />

repayment of the loan. This process has been adopted to calcul<strong>at</strong>e the<br />

time cost of one day <strong>for</strong> the fact th<strong>at</strong> the possibility of getting wage<br />

employment is rel<strong>at</strong>ively high during these periods. Since the<br />

agricultural term loans (particularly, <strong>for</strong> allied agricultural activity)<br />

have been obtained by a small proportion of sample households in the<br />

study area, <strong>and</strong> in many cases it has been given under the poverty<br />

allevi<strong>at</strong>ion scheme, we are not considering the transaction costs<br />

rel<strong>at</strong>ing to term loans in the analysis.<br />

Table 7.5 brings out th<strong>at</strong> the average transaction cost (ATC)<br />

decreased with increase in the size of holding. It is interesting to note<br />

th<strong>at</strong> the average transaction cost as percentage to average amount of<br />

loan also decreased with respect to increasing size of l<strong>and</strong>holding <strong>and</strong><br />

loan size. The effective r<strong>at</strong>e of interest was much more <strong>for</strong> small <strong>and</strong><br />

marginal farmers compared to medium <strong>and</strong> large size farms. The<br />

effective r<strong>at</strong>e of interest <strong>for</strong> 100 rupees of loan was 20.55 per cent <strong>for</strong><br />

the marginal farmer, whereas, it was 14.22 per cent <strong>for</strong> the large size


farmer. This shows th<strong>at</strong> the effective r<strong>at</strong>e of interest was much higher<br />

than th<strong>at</strong> of the bank r<strong>at</strong>e of interest <strong>for</strong> marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers.<br />

Table 7.5: Cost of Borrowing (Short·Term) from the Financial<br />

Institutions in the Study Area<br />

(Amounts in Rupees)<br />

Size of Average Average Interest Total ATe as G/o Effective R<strong>at</strong>e<br />

L<strong>and</strong>holding Amount Transaction Charges Cost of of Average of Interest <strong>for</strong><br />

(in Acres' of Loan Co<strong>at</strong> (ATe) <strong>for</strong> 12 Loans Amount of Rs.IOO of<br />

Months Loan Loan<br />

Up to 2.5 3,679 271 485 756 7. 37 20. 55<br />

12.51 - 5.00 7,909 269 1,046 1,314 3. 40 16. 62<br />

5.01- 10.0 11,752 234 1,542 1,776 1. 99 15. 12<br />

[10.01 <strong>and</strong> 20,926 241 2,735 2,976 1. 15 14. 22<br />

I Above<br />

. Average 11,373 252 1,493 1,745 2. 22 15. 34<br />

Source: Fleld Survey<br />

The cost of borrowing of institutional credit by farm households<br />

according to the size of t.l:!e loa..'1 in t..'1e study areas also reveals th<strong>at</strong><br />

the ATe as percentage of average borrowing cost (ABC) kept on<br />

decreasing with the increasing credit limit (Table 7.6). The ATe was<br />

34.1 per cent within the credit limit of up to Rs. 5,000, whereas, it<br />

drastically went down to 6.6 per cent <strong>for</strong> the credit limit of more than<br />

Rs. 20,000. Altern<strong>at</strong>ively, the average interest cost as percentage to<br />

average borrowing cost kept on increasing with the increasing size of<br />

the loan. The effective r<strong>at</strong>e of interest was much more <strong>for</strong> the lower<br />

size credit limit than the higher size of the loan. From Tables 7.5 <strong>and</strong><br />

7.6 it can be concluded th<strong>at</strong> the effective r<strong>at</strong>e of interest was inversely<br />

rel<strong>at</strong>ed with the size of holding <strong>and</strong> the credit limit. Based on the<br />

effective r<strong>at</strong>e of interest one can find th<strong>at</strong> the institutional credit is<br />

costly <strong>for</strong> marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers than the medium <strong>and</strong> large size<br />

farmers. Thus, the higher transaction costs not only increases the<br />

effective r<strong>at</strong>e of interest but also deters small borrowers from<br />

approaching <strong>for</strong>mal institutions <strong>for</strong> credit (see, Adams <strong>and</strong> Nehman<br />

(979).<br />

'I'


Table 7.6: Cost of Borrowing of <strong>Institutional</strong> Credit by Farm<br />

Households According to the Size of Loan in the Study Area<br />

(Amount In Rupees)<br />

I<br />

Average Average ATe as % Average TC Per Loan Size Size of Borrow- of Average Interest Rs. I<br />

Loan ing Cost Borrowing Cost as 100<br />

Cost % or<br />

or ABC Loan<br />

Up to 5,000 3,690 722 34.1 65.9 6.7<br />

5,001- 10,000 7,800 1,253 18.4 8l.6 3.0<br />

10,001 - 15,000 13,792 1,956 10.6 89.4 l.5<br />

15,001- 20,000 19,279 2,854 9.4 90.6 1.4<br />

; 20,001 & Above 37,611 5,315 6.6 93.4 0.9<br />

Note: ATC - Average Transaction Cost<br />

Average Borrowing Cost = ATC + Average Interest Payment<br />

Source: Field Survey<br />

\<br />

Effective<br />

Interest<br />

R<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong><br />

Rs. 100 of<br />

Loan<br />

19.6<br />

16.1<br />

14.2<br />

14.8<br />

14.1<br />

The Credit-Gap (CG)<br />

As we have noted earlier, borrowers st<strong>at</strong>ed th<strong>at</strong> the disbursed loan<br />

amounts were inadequ<strong>at</strong>e. If subsidised <strong>for</strong>mal credit is inadequ<strong>at</strong>e in<br />

supply, a market <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal credit is autom<strong>at</strong>ically cre<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

(Chaudhuri <strong>and</strong> Gupta 1996). Hence, this section is devoted to an<br />

analysis of the extent of credit-gap among farm households across size<br />

class of l<strong>and</strong>holdings.<br />

Table 7.7 demonstr<strong>at</strong>es the level of farm dependency on credit<br />

so as to meet the cost of production. Methodologically, this is based<br />

on the Cost A2 process65 (the method given by the Reports of the<br />

Commission <strong>for</strong> Agricultural Costs <strong>and</strong> Prices) to estim<strong>at</strong>e the cost of<br />

cultiv<strong>at</strong>ion. It can be seen th<strong>at</strong> per acre paid-out cost shows a positive<br />

associ<strong>at</strong>ion with the SIze of holding. Farm expenditure, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

corresponding credit this necessit<strong>at</strong>es, is of course depend upon<br />

6S Cost A2 z All actual expenses in cash <strong>and</strong> kind incurred in the production by the<br />

owner (Cost AI) + rent paid <strong>for</strong> leased-in l<strong>and</strong>. Since the objective of this study is<br />

not to highlight the cost of production, other methods which include imputed<br />

value of family labour, interest on value of owned capital assets (excluding l<strong>and</strong>).<br />

rental value of owned l<strong>and</strong> etc. have not been taken into account in the cost of<br />

production.


labour <strong>and</strong> technical input requirements (the extent to which labourpower<br />

employed is purchased, the use of fertiliser <strong>and</strong> pesticides,<br />

extent of mechanis<strong>at</strong>ion, <strong>and</strong> the type of crop grown).<br />

Table 7.7: Extent of Dependency on Credit Per Acre of Gross<br />

Cropped Area (2001-021<br />

Size of Holding Per Acre Paid- Level of Dependency on Credit<br />

(in Acres) Out Costs (in Per cent)<br />

(in Rs.) Total I Formal<br />

Advanced Region<br />

0.01- 2.50 1,823 64.95 26.04<br />

2.51 5.00 2,722 69.45 44.84<br />

5.01 10.00 3,543 68.36 35.92<br />

10.01 - Above 3,514 52.80 38.33<br />

Backward Region<br />

0.01- 2.50 1,662 58.66 26.19<br />

2.51 - 5.00 2,161 74.47 I 54.41<br />

S.Ul 10.00 2,242 64.01 38.60<br />

~ 10.01 - Above 2,622 48.91 35.34<br />

Source. Field survey<br />

i<br />

Not surprisingly, large size farmers depended less on credit to<br />

<strong>finance</strong> their production expenditure. This finding was also true <strong>for</strong><br />

marginal farmers when compared with small farmers. It is interesting<br />

to note th<strong>at</strong> among all the c<strong>at</strong>egories, only small farmers were covering<br />

a rel<strong>at</strong>ively higher proportion of their cost of production through<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal credit in both the regions of Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district. Although<br />

medium <strong>and</strong> large size farmers obtained higher absolute amounts of<br />

credit, the proportion of <strong>for</strong>mal credit in their overall production cost<br />

was small. In this connection, it must be emphasised th<strong>at</strong> while in<br />

absolute terms the flow of credit might indeed be positively associ<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

with the size of holding, it was inversely rel<strong>at</strong>ed as a proportion to the<br />

per acre cost of production in the study area. It seems, bankers were<br />

fixing a maximum credit limit irrespective of medium <strong>and</strong> large size<br />

farmers' production costs <strong>and</strong> the credit requirement.


A close observ<strong>at</strong>ion on the p<strong>at</strong>tern of credit flow reveals th<strong>at</strong><br />

these farmers in both the regions of Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district, managed to<br />

cover between 26 to 54 per cent of their total expenditure on<br />

agricultural production by means of <strong>for</strong>mal sources of credit. The<br />

<strong>for</strong>egoing analysis, there<strong>for</strong>e, suggests th<strong>at</strong> the flow of credit were<br />

insufficient to meet the production costs of peasant farmers engaged<br />

in cultiv<strong>at</strong>ion. To meet the remaining cost they turned either to self<strong>finance</strong><br />

(capital gener<strong>at</strong>ed from elsewhere in their total economic<br />

oper<strong>at</strong>ion or activity) or to borrowing from the in<strong>for</strong>mal market or both<br />

or may be remaining s<strong>at</strong>isfied with poor investment. In this context, it<br />

is essential to measure the magnitude of credit-gap.<br />

The credit-gap reJers to the unmet credit needs oj potential<br />

borrowers Jrom either Jormal or iri<strong>for</strong>mal or Jrom both the sectors with<br />

their respective term <strong>and</strong> conditions. The dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit is assumed<br />

to be positively rel<strong>at</strong>ed with area under oper<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> the requirement<br />

of working capital. In our analysis it is also assumed th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

maximum dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit could be equal to the paid-out cost (C t *)<br />

given the self-<strong>finance</strong> capacity of the farmer. Thus, one can expect<br />

th<strong>at</strong> the obtained amount of credit (C t ) S; C t *. If C t < C t * holds good,<br />

then there is a possibility of credit-gap. Altern<strong>at</strong>ively, given the self<strong>finance</strong>,<br />

when the required amount of credit <strong>for</strong> the project is not<br />

disbursed to the concerned borrower by the above sources, then the<br />

question of credit-gap comes.<br />

In this section, the credit-gap has been analysed with respect to<br />

size of l<strong>and</strong>holding within <strong>and</strong> across the regions. The credit-gap per<br />

acre of gross cropped area has been calcul<strong>at</strong>ed in two different ways.<br />

~mce the <strong>for</strong>mal credit is not enough, farmer borrowers are depending


upon in<strong>for</strong>mal credit market. Thus, given the self-<strong>finance</strong> 66 <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

credit the amount of in<strong>for</strong>mal credit taken per acre of gross cropped<br />

area can be tre<strong>at</strong>ed as the credit-gap. The calcul<strong>at</strong>ion of credit-gap on<br />

the basis of in<strong>for</strong>mal credit can be defined as the actual credit-gap. In<br />

the case of second method, credit-gap <strong>for</strong> each c<strong>at</strong>egory of farmers has<br />

been calcul<strong>at</strong>ed by taking the difference between the maximum paidout<br />

cost per acre of gross cropped area in the concerned region <strong>and</strong><br />

the actual paid-out cost. The second method seems to be more logical<br />

in the sense th<strong>at</strong>, ceteris paribus (viz., crop failure, pnces of<br />

agricultural product, clim<strong>at</strong>ic condition, risk factors, <strong>and</strong> so on), all<br />

c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers would have been interested to invest to the<br />

extent of maximum paid-out cost per acre in the respective regions<br />

provided the required amount of credit would have been available to<br />

them. The measurement of credit-gap on the basis of second method<br />

can be st<strong>at</strong>ed as the rel<strong>at</strong>ive credit-gap. The issue of rel<strong>at</strong>ive creditgap<br />

seems to be more prominent in the case of farmers those who are<br />

remaining s<strong>at</strong>isfied with poor investment due to lack of availability of<br />

credit from either or both the credit markets. The amount of creditgap<br />

per acre of gross cropped area has been presented in Table 7.8.<br />

It can be seen from Table 7.8 th<strong>at</strong> the actual credit-gap was<br />

more <strong>for</strong> the medium size farmers in both the regions. This could be<br />

<strong>at</strong>tributed to the high cost of production with less self-<strong>finance</strong> capacity<br />

as compared to large size farmers. For the rest of c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers<br />

the actual credit-gap was inversely rel<strong>at</strong>ed to the size of l<strong>and</strong>holdings.<br />

This could be mainly <strong>at</strong>tributed to a progressive self-<strong>finance</strong> capacity<br />

given the <strong>for</strong>mal credit. It can be seen from Table 7.8 th<strong>at</strong> the self<strong>finance</strong><br />

capacity per acre of gross cropped area shows a positive<br />

''', The self-<strong>finance</strong> capacity of a farmer can be defined as per acre paId-out cost of<br />

production less per acre <strong>for</strong>mal <strong>and</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal credit


associ<strong>at</strong>ion with size classes of holding. But can we rely on this self<strong>finance</strong><br />

capacity of the farm households. The distribution of self<strong>finance</strong><br />

capacity is given below in Table 7.9.<br />

Table 7.8: L<strong>and</strong>holding-wise Credit-Gap<br />

i ~'::~;~::n;~ I pr~:~~;;~n I c;:::~~r i IC::~~::e~~~:;~r~U;nt~~~~~:es)~e::~:~~<br />

lin Acres) I PAr' er ere 0 A ere 0 r' ; Cropped Acre of I Per Acre of: Gap<br />

I<br />

Gross Gross I Area = Gros s Gross<br />

Cropped Cropped I<br />

Actual Cropp ed Cropped I<br />

Mea Mea I Credit-Gllp __ Are a~~ __ ~'!!l _______ _<br />

Adv,,-~ce~ R~i() n<br />

0.01 - 2.50 1823 475<br />

, 70,) __,__ 1,18<br />

2.51 - 5.00 2,722 1,193 I 670 __ ~_,86 3' 859 ' 822<br />

7 - --1-, 086 ~:- - -0 - ~<br />

5.01 - 10.00 3,544 1,308 , 1,149_~_~~5 -------- - - ----\.-- - - - - --<br />

10.01& above 3514 1,347 509 I ,85<br />

I<br />

I<br />

I<br />

I<br />

1~~6i9=-~~>Ii _<br />

~ ___ 1,6~8_~ _ 39_<br />

All classes 3,289 1,249 I 7~E>_ _2,(j05 1,284 255<br />

Backward ~io<br />

10.01 - 2.S0 1662 435 540 97<br />

2.51 - 5.00 2 161 1 176 434<br />

I<br />

1,6<br />

'5.01 - 10.00 2,242 865 570 1,4<br />

10.01 & above 2,622 927 356 +--l,~ ~<br />

IAlI classes 2,331 915 446 1,3<br />

Note: Sample SIZe - 200, Ie = In<strong>for</strong>mal credIt<br />

Source: Field Survey<br />

Table 7.9 explains th<strong>at</strong> there was less vari<strong>at</strong>ion in the self-<strong>finance</strong><br />

capacity <strong>at</strong> different <strong>levels</strong> <strong>for</strong> each c<strong>at</strong>egory of farmers in the<br />

advanced region. This implies th<strong>at</strong> the self-<strong>finance</strong> capacity was<br />

proportional to the cost of production. In the case of backward region<br />

it seems to be progressive with respect to size of l<strong>and</strong>holdings. Based<br />

on this argument one can rely on the self-<strong>finance</strong> capacity of the<br />

farmer as defined above while calcul<strong>at</strong>ing the credit-gap.


Table 7.9: Self-<strong>finance</strong> Capacity of Farmers Per Acre of Gross<br />

Cropped Area<br />

Size class of"'-- ':- (1% 1 - 25 o/~·: 26 - 50 % Above 50 % Total Farmers<br />

la."dilolciings (iIl!cres)~ _ -=-__ ___ ~ __ Advanced Region<br />

O.01~2.50___ 16.1 22.6 32.3' 29.0 100 (31)<br />

2.5L~_5.00 - ---~]238-~ 28.6 j-19.1 .1- 28.6 100 (21)<br />

5.01- 10.00 . 19.2-15.4 -_. 30.S -- 34.6 100 (26)<br />

_~~~~1~~~~ Abo"~~-~--f;~;(~;~:8 _~~f~l~ .~:.:.= ;~:~- -. ;gg i;;~)<br />

___ ~ _________---,__ B",ckwar~ gegion_<br />

~~~; : ;:~g i ~g:~-+--~~~ j=-_J~}---+=-'K~ -_ ;gg g~; -<br />

O.o=t __ ZJ~ __ 5_0.0 __ 1 _ 42<br />

5.01 - 10.00 I 0.0 ~L3 __ 42.9 __--1__ 23.8 100 (21)<br />

..CJ -=--r 100 (14)<br />

,10.Ol<strong>and</strong> Above<br />

All classes<br />

Note: Figures in parenthesis indic<strong>at</strong>e the number of farm households.<br />

Source: Field Survey<br />

LI4.0_ . ...J4,-0--,---..lO


collected on the coping str<strong>at</strong>egy of the farmer borrowers to meet their<br />

requirement. The distribution of borrowers (with access to <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

loans) by number of sources of borrowing shows th<strong>at</strong> about 70.5 per<br />

cent of farmers went <strong>for</strong> two or more sources in the unorganised<br />

sector to meet their cost of production (Table 7.10). This shows th<strong>at</strong><br />

how far our <strong>for</strong>mal financial systems were good enough to cover the<br />

credit needs of farmer borrowers.<br />

Table 7.10: Distribution of Borrowers by Number of Sources of<br />

Borrowing<br />

I Number of Sources I Marginal: §maU_ 1<br />

Medium.~ - Large<br />

_ (in per cent)<br />

All Farmers<br />

___.___ _ \"ith Access t()Form.al_Lo_ans<br />

___ ~I_<br />

I. 2<br />

46.2 31.3 10.5<br />

46.-2-'-53.1--65. 8- -<br />

44.8<br />

51. '7<br />

295<br />

56 3<br />

3 7.7 12.5 21.1 3.-;;4c--_12.5<br />

4 <strong>and</strong>. Abc' .. e "" I ') 1 " C O. 0 .L. 0<br />

r-_-_ -_"-"_-::-._T:o_tal<br />

___ -=ocI:O~J_t:~J~~L __ ~9t -r _l~~L<br />

Without Access to Formal Loans<br />

._- ~--- --'--- -_.-- . - --- ---<br />

_____ 0 __ ~1_47.3 . ._5~_...:...._


their access to in<strong>for</strong>mal credit market was also hi"hl\' ,., . rl'strlctcci'<br />

This market oper<strong>at</strong>es on the basis of personalised rel<strong>at</strong>ionship. \\'hil'!J<br />

means th<strong>at</strong> anyone who is prepared to pay the interest r<strong>at</strong>l' <strong>and</strong> meet<br />

the coll<strong>at</strong>eral requirements, IS not likelY to reeel\T a loan<br />

autom<strong>at</strong>ically from all lenders (see Basu 1997). Man~'<br />

risk-averse<br />

lenders might not pmvide credit to certain borrowers, or use ercdll<br />

limit, due to the problem of moral hazard <strong>and</strong> ad\'erse selection (see<br />

Stiglitz <strong>and</strong> Weiss, 1981). There<strong>for</strong>e, given the poor access 10<br />

institutional credit <strong>and</strong> self-<strong>finance</strong> capacity of small <strong>and</strong> marginal<br />

farmers, the restricted access to in<strong>for</strong>mal credit market also contributed<br />

to a larger amount of rel<strong>at</strong>ive credit-gap.<br />

Thus, to underst<strong>and</strong> the<br />

coping str<strong>at</strong>egy, an analysis on the terms <strong>and</strong> conditions in in<strong>for</strong>mal<br />

credIt market IS needed.<br />

Type of Contracts in In<strong>for</strong>mal Credit Market<br />

In a rural community, a farmer can mobilise the amount of working<br />

capital by offering coll<strong>at</strong>eral, coll<strong>at</strong>eral substitutes, personal security<br />

<strong>and</strong> personalised rel<strong>at</strong>ionship, <strong>and</strong> through third party guarantor. An<br />

important issue in this regard is th<strong>at</strong> credit is invariably r<strong>at</strong>ioned<br />

according to the ability of the borrowers to offer coll<strong>at</strong>eral (Sarap<br />

1991). The types of contracts in the in<strong>for</strong>mal credit market under<br />

different <strong>for</strong>ms of coll<strong>at</strong>eral security are further discussed below.<br />

(a) Contract with Coll<strong>at</strong>eral<br />

The lender's preference <strong>for</strong> an asset, as coll<strong>at</strong>eral. depends on<br />

the effective r<strong>at</strong>e of return he expects from the sale value of assets. in<br />

case of default of loan. Thus, higher the market value of a cull<strong>at</strong>l'f,d<br />

asset, higher will be loan amount to a borrower. Similarl\·. higher the<br />

" This finding also collabor<strong>at</strong>es \nth the earlier study mane by HaSLl I; (fll!!<br />

lOR


assets position of the borrowers (which tent<strong>at</strong>ively represent his credit<br />

worthiness), higher would be the amount of loan he can arrange (sec,<br />

Sarap 1991). In a loan transaction the requirement of coll<strong>at</strong>eral arises<br />

since it shifts the potential capital loss from the lender to the<br />

borrowers (Binswanger <strong>and</strong> Rosenzweig 1986).<br />

(bl Contract with Coll<strong>at</strong>eral Substitutes<br />

In the absence of marketable coll<strong>at</strong>eral, the borrower uses<br />

coll<strong>at</strong>eral substitutes or inferior coll<strong>at</strong>eral to mobilise the loans. In<br />

such deals, the lenders provide credit to the borrower against his<br />

commitment of future sale of labour service or crops to him. For this<br />

kind of contract, the borrower provides his labour services <strong>at</strong> the call<br />

of the iender <strong>at</strong> an agreed wage r<strong>at</strong>e or sell his crops to him <strong>at</strong> a predetermined<br />

price in a mutually agreed time to repay the loan (Bard han<br />

<strong>and</strong> Rudra 1978). Hence, in the case of without coll<strong>at</strong>eral, the farmer<br />

borrower can obtain credit from the interlocked credit market.<br />

However, different <strong>for</strong>ms of welfare loss of the borrower is<br />

inevitable in the interlocked credit contract since it allows the lender<br />

to extract full surplus <strong>at</strong>tributable to the inter-locked market<br />

(Bardhan 1984 <strong>and</strong> 1989; Gangopadhyay <strong>and</strong> Sengupta 1987;<br />

Gangopadhyay 1997). This extract in inter-locked credit market can<br />

be noticed usually in the <strong>for</strong>m of under valu<strong>at</strong>ion of labour services<br />

<strong>and</strong> output of the borrowers <strong>and</strong> overvalu<strong>at</strong>ion of inputs supplied by<br />

the lenders. Thus, given the worse access to organised credit market<br />

<strong>and</strong> self-<strong>finance</strong> capacity, if the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> additional liquidity to<br />

meet the working capital is rel<strong>at</strong>ively inelastic in n<strong>at</strong>ure, the borro\\'ers<br />

may st<strong>and</strong> <strong>at</strong> the receiving end of the bargaining process in the interlocked<br />

credit market. Altern<strong>at</strong>ively, the terms <strong>and</strong> conditions become


favourable to the lender. There<strong>for</strong>e, the degree of extraction Illa\' \'an<br />

from borrO\\'er to borrower depending upon the bargaining cap'tcit\<br />

between borrowers <strong>and</strong> lenders. The pre-determined exchange' rail' in<br />

the inter-locked credit contract <strong>and</strong> the extent of extraction has hcen<br />

discussed in the subsequent sub-section.<br />

c) With Personal Security <strong>and</strong>/or Third Partv Guarantor<br />

In the absence of acceptable coll<strong>at</strong>eral by the lender or<br />

interlinked deal, the borrowers mobilise credit through personal<br />

security or third party guarantor. In the <strong>for</strong>mer case, the lender may<br />

provide loans to those borrowers from whom he is sure of repaymeI1l<br />

or able to recover the loan through some implicit or explicit<br />

mcchanism 68 . Elsc:w-lLere, it. IS argued th<strong>at</strong> loan contract \\'ithout<br />

coll<strong>at</strong>eral increased with the raise in the st<strong>at</strong>us 69 of the borrowers<br />

(Sarap 1991). In such a case, the preference of the lender was based<br />

on caste, kinship connection, <strong>and</strong> the localities of the borrowers with<br />

which the lender may have some ties (see Bardhan <strong>and</strong> Rudra 1978).<br />

These connections <strong>and</strong> in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion about the borrowers worked as a<br />

system of guarantee <strong>for</strong> the repayment of the loans. The l<strong>at</strong>ter case.<br />

the third party acted as a guarantor, exerted pressure/ influenced the<br />

borrower <strong>for</strong> repayment of the loans. Thus, the third part~· worked as<br />

peer monitor 70 in borrower selection as well as <strong>for</strong> the repayment of<br />

the loan.<br />

" This mechanism could be social sanctIOn against the defaulter or loss of luturc<br />

borro\\'ing from the same or other lcnders. For more dct<strong>at</strong>led discuSSiOll. see,<br />

Pl<strong>at</strong>teau <strong>and</strong> Abrahem (1987); Basu (1986,1989); Sarap 11991).<br />

, This st<strong>at</strong>us may be In the <strong>for</strong>m of l<strong>and</strong>holding, assets pOSItion. <strong>and</strong> other SlH'J()­<br />

economic st<strong>at</strong>us.<br />

See, Stiglitz 11990),<br />

)()()


Interest R<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> Different <strong>for</strong>ms of Contracts in In<strong>for</strong>mal Credit<br />

Market<br />

The interest r<strong>at</strong>e in the in<strong>for</strong>mal credit market depends upon the kll1ci<br />

of contracts with or without coll<strong>at</strong>eral. Interestingly, the rdlt' "I'<br />

interest also varies across the quality <strong>and</strong> marketability of the<br />

coll<strong>at</strong>eraL In the case of loan contract with coll<strong>at</strong>eral, the kndcr<br />

generally aseertams the sale pnce of the piece of coll<strong>at</strong>eral assets<br />

be<strong>for</strong>e providing a loan. If a particular piece of coll<strong>at</strong>eral asset im·oh·es<br />

higher transaction costs while selling, then the interest r<strong>at</strong>es on loans<br />

taken by pledging such coll<strong>at</strong>eral were more. For instance, tIl(' cost<br />

involved in selling <strong>for</strong> an asset like old bicycle or utensils is very high<br />

than gold. There<strong>for</strong>e, the asset, which has either low resale value or<br />

involves high transaction costs in selling, the lender either prondes a<br />

very small amount of loan with higher interest r<strong>at</strong>e or may not accept<br />

the asset as security. Contrary to this, if the lender expects a high<br />

resale value of an asset (<strong>for</strong> example l<strong>and</strong> or gold) in future, then he<br />

may be willing to provide a higher size of loan. Thus, <strong>for</strong> poor quality<br />

of coll<strong>at</strong>eral assets the terms <strong>and</strong> conditions are more harsh to<br />

borrowers in terms of r<strong>at</strong>e of interest charged, under valu<strong>at</strong>ion of<br />

assets <strong>and</strong> dur<strong>at</strong>ion of the loan as compared to borrowing against gold<br />

or l<strong>and</strong> (see Basu 1989; Sarap 1990, 1991). For poor quality of<br />

coll<strong>at</strong>eral (say brass utensils) the interest r<strong>at</strong>e vary from 60 per cent to<br />

120 per cent, whereas <strong>for</strong> good quality of coll<strong>at</strong>eral like gold the<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>e vary from 24 per cent to 48 per cent per annum.<br />

Generally, the loan contract with coll<strong>at</strong>eral substitutes<br />

(interlocked credit transaction) does not involve any interest r<strong>at</strong>c.<br />

However, under valu<strong>at</strong>ion of labour service <strong>and</strong> output or the<br />

borrowers <strong>and</strong> overvalu<strong>at</strong>ion of inputs supplied bv the lenders lS the<br />

201


common practice in this kind of credit transaction. The asyml11ctn' of<br />

in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion, moral hazard <strong>and</strong> adverse selection problems along \\'ith<br />

the degree of risk involved in lending (<strong>for</strong> instance, crop failure in the<br />

case of credit-output interlocked transaction) insists the lender to fix<br />

up a low price <strong>for</strong> coll<strong>at</strong>eral substitutes. Hence, it is the r<strong>at</strong>e of return<br />

through low price <strong>for</strong> borrower's output in the interlocked credit<br />

transaction compens<strong>at</strong>es the interest income loss th<strong>at</strong> would have<br />

been received by the lender in altern<strong>at</strong>ive investment. Given this,<br />

credit (either cash or kind) can be interlocked \\'ith either labour or<br />

product markets where prices are predetermined.<br />

The interest r<strong>at</strong>e on loan transaction against personal security<br />

kind), volume of credit, the personal rel<strong>at</strong>ionship with the lender, <strong>and</strong><br />

the socio-economic st<strong>at</strong>us of the borrower. In this system, the<br />

borrowers repay the loans ll1 terms of either cash or kind <strong>at</strong> the<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>es, which was frxed <strong>at</strong> the time of taking loan. For kind<br />

repayment, both the parties jointly determine the prices of the<br />

products <strong>at</strong> the time of repayment, given the present market situ<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

of the product <strong>and</strong> bargaining capacity of both the parties. It has been<br />

observed in the study areas th<strong>at</strong> the lender charges a rel<strong>at</strong>i\'Ch' low<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> the kind component of loans 7 ) (say fertiliser or<br />

pesticides) than the cash component. Given the credil\\'orthiness of<br />

the borrower, the high competition among the fertiliser <strong>and</strong> pesticide<br />

traders in selling can be <strong>at</strong>tributed to the low interest r<strong>at</strong>e charged <strong>for</strong><br />

kind component of loan. The other type of kind component loan like<br />

paddy, the interest r<strong>at</strong>e charged is 50 per cent of the principal. The<br />

dur<strong>at</strong>ion of loan of this type is generally six months or less. Bor[i)wing<br />

"I For instance, farmers take fertiliser <strong>and</strong> pestlcicies as credit <strong>at</strong> some 1Il11";-CS' r;l~('<br />

from the shopkeeper, <strong>and</strong> they repa,\" it after haryest.<br />

202


203<br />

of paddy loan decreases with the rise in the st<strong>at</strong>us of the households<br />

(see, Sarap 1991). Since money has wide scope <strong>for</strong> in\,cstmt:nt, the<br />

lender charges a high interest r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> the loan borrowed in cash. The<br />

farmer borrowers in the study areas st<strong>at</strong>ed th<strong>at</strong> the interest raIl' on<br />

kind component of loan varied from 48 per cent to 60 per cent,<br />

whereas it varied from 48 to 120 per cent <strong>for</strong> cash component of<br />

loans.<br />

Thus, under the type of contracts agreed upon by the borrowers<br />

<strong>and</strong> lenders the degree of variability in the level of interest r<strong>at</strong>e can be<br />

as high as 120 per cent or as low as zero per cent per annum (Rudra<br />

1982). Bhaduri (1977) argues th<strong>at</strong> usurious interest r<strong>at</strong>es are the<br />

result of monopoly power of the lender. Bottomley (1975) mentions<br />

th<strong>at</strong> high interest r<strong>at</strong>e reflects the risk of default faced by the lender in<br />

the rural credit market of the less developed countries. The other<br />

studies 72 claim th<strong>at</strong> the presence of interlocked contracts can explain<br />

the existence of a wide spectrum of interest r<strong>at</strong>es. On the whole, it is<br />

the kind of contracts with or without coll<strong>at</strong>eral th<strong>at</strong> determine the<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>e in the in<strong>for</strong>mal credit market.<br />

With this background, it may be useful to analyse the degree of<br />

extraction, the number of loan contracts <strong>and</strong> the amount of loan<br />

borrowed against different <strong>for</strong>m of coll<strong>at</strong>eral <strong>and</strong> type of contracts in<br />

in<strong>for</strong>mal credit market being undertaken as coping str<strong>at</strong>egy to meet<br />

the cost of production.<br />

-2 For more detailed discussion, see, Brn.\'cman ann Srinl\"(lSan 119811, \11t1"d Ill)S?,I.<br />

<strong>and</strong> Basu (1983).


Borrowing Against Different Coll<strong>at</strong>eral as Coping Str<strong>at</strong>egy<br />

In the study area, interlocked credit <strong>and</strong> product transaction \\'


However, the details of income loss due to interlocked credit<br />

have been shown in Table 7.12. This has been estim<strong>at</strong>ed by obtainl11g<br />

the quantity sold <strong>at</strong> interlocked price as against the hypothetical<br />

scenario of selling the same quantity <strong>at</strong> the open market <strong>and</strong><br />

minimum support price (MSP). The second <strong>and</strong> third column of Table<br />

7.12 shows th<strong>at</strong> both interlocked <strong>and</strong> the open market price73 differed<br />

across the farmers with different size of l<strong>and</strong>holdings. It is seen th<strong>at</strong><br />

the medium <strong>and</strong> large size farmers had better bargain in fIXing not just<br />

the interlocked price but also in obtaining a favourable price in the open<br />

market. Poor bargaining capacity due to high intensity of credit<br />

compelled the marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers to sell <strong>at</strong> low price in the<br />

interlocked credit market.<br />

Table 7.12. Regions & L<strong>and</strong>holding-wise Estim<strong>at</strong>ed Income<br />

Loss Per Bag of Selling Paddy due to Interlocked Credit<br />

Market in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i District, Orissa 2001-02\<br />

Size of Interlocked Open LPJ LP, , Income Loss Income Loss L<strong>and</strong>holding Price Market in Rs. in Rs. in Situ<strong>at</strong>ion in Situ<strong>at</strong>ion I<br />

(in Acres) In Ra/bac Price (A) fBI A B<br />

in R<strong>at</strong>bag _lin %) iin%l<br />

Advanced R


credit market - principally when substantial amounts of this<br />

commodity (acquired from smallholders <strong>at</strong> pre-determined low prices)<br />

are marketed simultaneously - it is less than th<strong>at</strong> of marginal <strong>and</strong><br />

small farmers. Table 7.12 confirms both th<strong>at</strong> medium <strong>and</strong> large<br />

farmers receive a higher price <strong>for</strong> their paddy in the open market than<br />

do marginal <strong>and</strong> small producers, <strong>and</strong> also th<strong>at</strong> the difference between<br />

the interlocked price <strong>and</strong> the minimum support price <strong>for</strong> this crop<br />

declines with respect to l<strong>and</strong>holding size. The magnitude of income<br />

loss, however, depends on the extent of dependency on in<strong>for</strong>mal credit<br />

sources to meet working capital <strong>and</strong> also on the quantity of paddy<br />

sold <strong>at</strong> the pre-determined price. Wh<strong>at</strong> this underlines is th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

supply of <strong>for</strong>mal credit is itself inadequ<strong>at</strong>e to meet the needs of<br />

peasant farmers in both regions of Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district. Thus, given the<br />

self-<strong>finance</strong>, adequ<strong>at</strong>e availability of <strong>for</strong>mal credit could have<br />

minimised the income loss of the farmers who had taken loan from<br />

interlocked credit market.<br />

It is found th<strong>at</strong> the in<strong>for</strong>mal credit with coll<strong>at</strong>eral substitutes<br />

was not the only way to meet the cost of production. The farmers had<br />

also mobilised credit through other coll<strong>at</strong>eral such as l<strong>and</strong>, gold, brass<br />

utensils, output, personal security, <strong>and</strong> third party guarantor. Loan<br />

transactions against these coll<strong>at</strong>erals have been shown in Table 7.13.<br />

Table 7.13 shows th<strong>at</strong> 37 per cent of the loans <strong>and</strong> 35 per cent<br />

of total loan amount was borrowed by small farmers by keeping farm<br />

output as coll<strong>at</strong>eral. In such cases of inter-linked markets, the r<strong>at</strong>e of<br />

extraction was more. Against output, the marginal size farmers \\Tre<br />

having 19 per cent of their total loan contracts consisting of 1 P, per<br />

cent of the total loan borrowed. Probably, low base of output


production \\·as inhibiting the marginal iarmers to approach ttw<br />

lenders against output as coll<strong>at</strong>eral. These percentages dccreased<br />

progressively <strong>for</strong> the medium <strong>and</strong> large size farmers as compared to<br />

small farmers since they could mobilise in<strong>for</strong>mal credit \,·ith<br />

altern<strong>at</strong>ive contracts <strong>at</strong> low interest r<strong>at</strong>e. Use of gold as coll<strong>at</strong>eral rose<br />

with the increase in the st<strong>at</strong>us of borrowers. Poorer farm households<br />

utilised brass utensils as coll<strong>at</strong>eral in the absence of other altern<strong>at</strong>i\·e<br />

assets, where under valu<strong>at</strong>ion of assets <strong>and</strong> r<strong>at</strong>e of interests were<br />

high. The marginal farmers were having 21 of their total loan<br />

contracts against brass utensils. Borrowing (cash/ kind) against<br />

without coll<strong>at</strong>eral, where the interest r<strong>at</strong>es were high, declined with<br />

the rise in the st<strong>at</strong>us of farm households. The decline was more<br />

pronounced in the case of large farmers possible due to their own<br />

surplus <strong>and</strong> their better access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit (see Sarap 1990).<br />

Table 7.13: Farm Size <strong>and</strong> Coll<strong>at</strong>eral-wise Percentage of Loan<br />

Contracts <strong>and</strong> Percentae:e of Loan (amountl Borrowed<br />

Type of No. of Loan Contracts (%) Amount of Loan (%<br />

Coll<strong>at</strong>eral Marginal Small Medium Large Marginal Small Medium Large<br />

Offered<br />

Farmers Farmers Farmers Farmers Farmers Farmers Farmers FaTmers<br />

L<strong>and</strong> - 1.5 - - 1.2<br />

Gold 10.0 26.3 37.9 48.3 134 33.8 41.7 46.2<br />

Brass utensils 21.4 1.8 . 10 1 1.3 - -<br />

Output 18.6 36.8 31.8 31.0 17.7 34.8 29.6 27.1<br />

Sub-total 50.0 64.9 71.2 79.3 41.2 69.9 72.6 73.3<br />

Personal 30.0 33.3 28.8 20.7 37.9 29.0 27.4 26. I<br />

Security lal<br />

Third party 20.0 1.8 - - 20.9 1.1 -<br />

Iguarantor -Ibl<br />

Without colla- 50.0 35. I 28.8 20.7 588 30.1 27.4 26.7<br />

teral (a+ bl<br />

Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 ](1(l<br />

T<br />

170) 157) (66) (29) 63,340" 110.700' 320.800' 234,05'.-i<br />

Note: I. F,gures in parentheses represent the total number of loan contracts b\ thf'<br />

respectl\'e size of farms.<br />

2. 'represents the total amount of in<strong>for</strong>mal credit by the respectl\'e f~nOl<br />

groups.<br />

3. (-) means th<strong>at</strong> there was no in\"oh"ement of a size group of farm hOllsehok~<br />

<strong>for</strong> borrowing against a particular coll<strong>at</strong>erai.<br />

Source: Field Surw\·<br />

I<br />

:


Besides, this c<strong>at</strong>egory of farmers was having alternali\'(' assets to<br />

mobilise loans from in<strong>for</strong>mal sector <strong>at</strong> cheaper r<strong>at</strong>e. The percentage oj"<br />

loan lamount; borrowed against personal seeuntv <strong>and</strong> third part\"<br />

guarantor <strong>for</strong> marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers were 59 <strong>and</strong> 30 per cent<br />

respectively.<br />

On the whole, the composition of borrowing against different<br />

coll<strong>at</strong>er<strong>at</strong>es provided some characteristics of different borrowers in the<br />

sample. First, it shows th<strong>at</strong> the quality of coll<strong>at</strong>eral increased with the<br />

rise in the st<strong>at</strong>us of borrowers. Second, in the absence of altern<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

assets the small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers were compelled to mobilise<br />

funds <strong>at</strong> higher r<strong>at</strong>e of interest from in<strong>for</strong>mal credit market.<br />

Conclusions<br />

The analysis on credit delivery system shows th<strong>at</strong> most of the<br />

agricultural borrowers faced one or the other problem during as well<br />

as after obtaining loans. It is also observed th<strong>at</strong> these problems were<br />

more prominent in the case of marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers. The<br />

analysis on time taken to get a loan sanctioned shows an inverse<br />

rel<strong>at</strong>ionship with the size of l<strong>and</strong>holdings. Added to th<strong>at</strong>, the loan<br />

amounts were inadequ<strong>at</strong>e. This indic<strong>at</strong>es the strong practice of nonprice<br />

credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning in the provision of agricultural credit <strong>and</strong> in<br />

fixing the credit limit to agricultural borrowers. Since the <strong>for</strong>mal credit<br />

delivery system in the study area was found to be neither adequ<strong>at</strong>e<br />

nor timely, it could be argued th<strong>at</strong> the Gupta Committee<br />

recommend<strong>at</strong>ions have not been successful in improving the qualIty of<br />

credit delivery system in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district of Orissa.<br />

')rL~


The analysis on borrO\\'ing costs <strong>for</strong> agricultural credit s!Jo\\'s<br />

th<strong>at</strong> the effectl\'e r<strong>at</strong>e of interest \\'as in\'L~rseh' rel<strong>at</strong>ed \nth the size u1<br />

l<strong>and</strong>holdings <strong>and</strong> the credit limit. Based on the effective r<strong>at</strong>e of<br />

interest one could find th<strong>at</strong> the institutional credit \\'as cost!\' fur<br />

marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers than the medium <strong>and</strong> large size farmers,<br />

The terms <strong>and</strong> conditions of loan obtained against different<br />

coll<strong>at</strong>eral assets indic<strong>at</strong>e th<strong>at</strong> the terms of getting loan became more<br />

unfavourable with the decline in the quality of coll<strong>at</strong>eral assets<br />

provided by the borrowers, Given the n<strong>at</strong>ure of in<strong>for</strong>mal credit market<br />

<strong>and</strong> the effective mechanism of controls on borrowers, the lender was<br />

in a position to extract as much as possible through higher interest<br />

r<strong>at</strong>e charges <strong>and</strong> other terms <strong>and</strong> conditlOns of the loan,<br />

An ob\'ious policy implic<strong>at</strong>ion th<strong>at</strong> can be drawn from this<br />

analysis is th<strong>at</strong> any move by the government to reduce imperfection in<br />

the credit market will benefit the farmer. In order to reduce the credit·<br />

gap problem, a rethinking on the scale of <strong>finance</strong> is needed,<br />

Nevertheless, a separ<strong>at</strong>e scale of <strong>finance</strong> should be fixed <strong>for</strong> each<br />

service area of the concerned bank since the cost of production vanes<br />

across the regions, Improved quality of credit delivery system with<br />

adequ<strong>at</strong>e loan amount can reduce farmers' dependence on in<strong>for</strong>mal<br />

sector to meet the cost of production, <strong>and</strong> in turn, the degree of<br />

extraction in the <strong>for</strong>m of interest <strong>and</strong> others especially from small <strong>and</strong><br />

marginal farmers,


Chapter 8<br />

SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS<br />

Introduction<br />

A majority of the peasant cultiv<strong>at</strong>ors 111 India find borrO\\·ing<br />

necessary, as their own farm savings are inadequ<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> both<br />

financing their various agricultural activities, <strong>and</strong> in carrying out<br />

improvements in productivity of their agricultural oper<strong>at</strong>ions (Lipton<br />

1976; Donald 1976; Sarap 1990). The provision of <strong>for</strong>mal credit to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> has been, there<strong>for</strong>e, central to the concern of planners <strong>and</strong><br />

development economists 111 post-independent India. A number of<br />

policies have been made to instil social responsibility 111 the <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

financial institutions to extend credit to rural households, in general.<br />

<strong>and</strong> farm households, in particular. These policies have succeeded in<br />

establishing a vast network of financial institutions 111 the<br />

countryside, <strong>and</strong> helped to spread the banking culture among in rural<br />

areas. But, quantit<strong>at</strong>ive progress <strong>at</strong> the cost of quality (Shivamaggi<br />

2000), high cost structure of oper<strong>at</strong>ions in rural areas <strong>and</strong> mounting<br />

overdues became a thre<strong>at</strong> to the viability of the financial institutions.<br />

Consequently, the policy of competitive financial system was adopted<br />

from 1991 onwards in the provision of agricultural credit to impro\,


the access of farmers, especially sll1


Trends in the Credit Flow <strong>at</strong> AII-Illdia Leliel alld COlltributing Factors<br />

The third chapter, which analysed the trends in the suppl\ of<br />

agricultural credit by SCBs <strong>at</strong> the all India level, revealed th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

proportion of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> to the net bank credit rapidly<br />

declined during the re<strong>for</strong>m period. The growth r<strong>at</strong>es of agricultuml<br />

credit were uneven across the sub-periods (pre- <strong>and</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m years) as<br />

well as across the bank groups. The supply of credit to this sector in<br />

both absolute <strong>and</strong> real terms grew <strong>at</strong> much faster r<strong>at</strong>e during the prere<strong>for</strong>m<br />

period as compared to the re<strong>for</strong>m period. Across the bank<br />

groups also, a similar p<strong>at</strong>tern could be observed. Further, the<br />

Scheduled Commercial Banks (SCBs) did not even reach the targets<br />

set by the government.<br />

As far as the factors determining the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

were concerned, the regression analysis showed th<strong>at</strong> credit flO\\, to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>at</strong> all-India level was adversely affected by investment ll1<br />

securities, credit subsidy, agricultural credit provided by co-oper<strong>at</strong>i\'es<br />

<strong>and</strong> interest r<strong>at</strong>e on lending, However, credit supply to <strong>agriculture</strong> \\'as<br />

positively associ<strong>at</strong>ed with number of rural bank branches,<br />

The better-off farmers had better access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit as<br />

compared to small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers, Importantly, despite the<br />

increasing consensus to extend credit facility to <strong>agriculture</strong>, in<br />

general, <strong>and</strong> small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers, in particular, banks were<br />

unable to lend to those activities with high social return or those<br />

c<strong>at</strong>egory of creditworthy borrowers who had been traditionall\'<br />

marginalised in the credit market.


Trends <strong>and</strong> Determinants of Credit FlolU to AgnclIilllrc ur 3lale <strong>and</strong><br />

District Level<br />

An analysis of trends in the supply of agricultural crCdlt \),. SCBs al<br />

the st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> district level has been carried out in the fourth chapIn<br />

The r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>at</strong> which credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> was disbursed gr-cw <strong>at</strong> a rapid<br />

r<strong>at</strong>e during the pre-re<strong>for</strong>m period as compared to the re<strong>for</strong>m pniod in<br />

most of the st<strong>at</strong>es. These growth r<strong>at</strong>es were found to be unevcn both<br />

during the sub-periods <strong>and</strong> across the st<strong>at</strong>es. An anal\·sis of l\m<br />

indic<strong>at</strong>ors, viz., the proportion of agricultural credit to net bank cred,t.<br />

<strong>and</strong> total bank deposits, revealed th<strong>at</strong> there were substantial interst<strong>at</strong>e<br />

differences in these indic<strong>at</strong>ors within <strong>and</strong> across the su b­<br />

periods. A decline in the proportion of agricultural credit to total bank<br />

deposits in all the major st<strong>at</strong>es implies th<strong>at</strong> the banks were diverting<br />

their funds raised in the <strong>for</strong>m of deposits to sectors other than<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>. This is found to be more prominent in the back"'ard<br />

st<strong>at</strong>es of Bihar, Uttar Pradesh <strong>and</strong> West Bengal.<br />

An analysis on access to credit (i.e., the number of farmers<br />

obtaining <strong>for</strong>mal credit to total number of farmers <strong>at</strong> a particular point<br />

of time) showed th<strong>at</strong> there were substantial inter-st<strong>at</strong>e differences in<br />

the access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit by the same c<strong>at</strong>egory of farmers <strong>at</strong> different<br />

points of time. While the percentages of farmers accessing <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

credit declined during the study period in most of the sta tcs, the loan<br />

amount per account increased. This implies th<strong>at</strong> there was<br />

concentr<strong>at</strong>ion of <strong>for</strong>mal loans in fa\'our of a particular group of<br />

borrowers, <strong>and</strong> th<strong>at</strong> the banks practised both price <strong>and</strong> non-pnce<br />

credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning methods rn the borro\\'er selection <strong>and</strong> fixdlIon of the<br />

credit limit. The non-prrce r<strong>at</strong>ioning bccomcs c\'


class of l<strong>and</strong>holding obtained substantialh difkrent loan amounts<br />

across the st<strong>at</strong>es.<br />

It is observed th<strong>at</strong> most of the findings <strong>at</strong> the district ltTcI<br />

converged with the st<strong>at</strong>e level analysis. The notable similarities in the<br />

findings rel<strong>at</strong>ing to the st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> district <strong>levels</strong> analysis were the<br />

declining share of agricultural credit from net bank credit. uneven<br />

credit flow across regions <strong>and</strong> the differences in the availability of<br />

credit per hectare of gross cropped area. This suggests th<strong>at</strong> the flow oi<br />

agricultural credit followed similar p<strong>at</strong>terns <strong>at</strong> both st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> district<br />

<strong>levels</strong>.<br />

Higher (or lower) the proportion of net bank credit to the<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> sector does not necessarily mean th<strong>at</strong> the per capita credit<br />

availability per hectare of gross cropped area was more (or less) in a<br />

particular st<strong>at</strong>e or district. Since the proportion of net bank credit<br />

does not take the gross cropped area into account, it might be difficult<br />

to draw a conclusion on whether or not a particular st<strong>at</strong>e or district<br />

was better off in terms of the availability of agricultural credit.<br />

There<strong>for</strong>e, credit (obtained from institutional agencies) per hectare of<br />

gross cropped area was used as an indic<strong>at</strong>or to measure the vari<strong>at</strong>ions<br />

in the supply of agricultural credit in the st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> district level<br />

analvsis. Variables such as area under irrig<strong>at</strong>ion, area under<br />

commercial crops to gross cropped area, Credit Deposit R<strong>at</strong>io (CDR)<br />

<strong>and</strong> density of bank branches per 1,000 farmers were specified as<br />

determinants of credit per hectare of gross cropped area <strong>for</strong> the<br />

regression analysis <strong>at</strong> both st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> district <strong>levels</strong>.


Since different st<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong> districts have different ch"r;ll'lt',']stJ('s<br />

111 terms of irrig<strong>at</strong>ion facilit\', area under commercial em!,,,. lTcdil<br />

deposit r<strong>at</strong>io <strong>and</strong> density of bank branches, panel regression \IdS Liscci<br />

to assess the separ<strong>at</strong>e effect of these variables, Based on the<br />

Langrange Multiplier st<strong>at</strong>istics <strong>and</strong> Hausman specific<strong>at</strong>ion lest, the<br />

Fixed Effect Model over R<strong>and</strong>om Effect Model was preferred "t Stall'<br />

level analysis, On the other h<strong>and</strong>. R<strong>and</strong>om Effect Model ,,'as useo in<br />

the district level analysis,<br />

The proportion of irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area to gross cropped area <strong>and</strong> credit<br />

deposit r<strong>at</strong>io were found to be the most signifIcant explan<strong>at</strong>ory<br />

variables <strong>for</strong> the vari<strong>at</strong>ions in the credit flow per hectare of gross<br />

cropped area in 14 major st<strong>at</strong>es as well as districts within Orissa,<br />

While the rel<strong>at</strong>ionship between the credit per hectare of gross cropped<br />

area <strong>and</strong> the <strong>for</strong>mer was positive, th<strong>at</strong> with the l<strong>at</strong>ter \\'as negau\'l',<br />

Since assured irrig<strong>at</strong>ion reduced crop uncertainty, bankers were<br />

probably giving priority to lend more to farmers with irng<strong>at</strong>eo<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>, Surprisingly, even when CDR increased, it reduccd the<br />

supply of credit. The neg<strong>at</strong>ive sign of CDR could be <strong>at</strong>tributed to<br />

perception among bankers th<strong>at</strong> loans to <strong>agriculture</strong> charactt'rised<br />

high-risk. The density of bank branches positivel" affected the credit<br />

flow per hectare of gross cropped area <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level. Although, this<br />

variable had positive associ<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>at</strong> the district level, it \\'as not<br />

significant. The coeffIcient of area under commercial crops to gross<br />

cropped area was positive but not signifIcant <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e len'!.<br />

However, this variable was neg<strong>at</strong>ive <strong>and</strong> highl\' significant ,,\ t 111'<br />

district leve!. On the whole, the st<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> district InTI "',,,1\sls<br />

suggest th<strong>at</strong> <strong>for</strong> improved flo\\' of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong>, tl1


aimed <strong>at</strong> Skppll1g up of the CDR should be backed \)\ (hilS,' OJ)<br />

improving irrig<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> banking infrastructure.<br />

Oper<strong>at</strong>ion of Macro Policy <strong>at</strong> the Micro Level: An AIlCilllSIS of Crcdlf Flou:<br />

in the Sample Bank Branches<br />

After 1991. the scope of the pnonty sector was broaclcned to lI1dudc<br />

activities, which were traditionally excluded from the pun'ie\\ of this<br />

sector. The fifth chapter has concentr<strong>at</strong>ed on an analysis of the<br />

impact of broadening the coverage of priority sectors on credit flo\\" to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>at</strong> the bank branch level in developed <strong>and</strong> backward<br />

blocks in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district, Orissa. Based on the d<strong>at</strong>a <strong>for</strong> tlw last fin'<br />

years ending with 2000-01, the following results haye been arnved: (il<br />

The share of priority sector from total bank advance had 1l1creased 111<br />

both the regions, whereas the share of credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> had<br />

declined during the same period. (ii) The bankers were gIving<br />

preference to non-agricultural activities especially in the advanced<br />

region. Although the volume of disbursement of agricultural credit by<br />

the sample bank branches in the advanced region \vas more, rd<strong>at</strong>ively<br />

gre<strong>at</strong>er share of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> from total advances was noticed<br />

<strong>for</strong> the sample bank branches of the backward region. The interest<br />

ll1come on total advance <strong>and</strong> type of securitY-\\'ise supply of<br />

agricultural credit were calcul<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>for</strong> both the regIOns <strong>for</strong><br />

corrobor<strong>at</strong>ing the above. It was found th<strong>at</strong> the interest income on<br />

total advances <strong>and</strong> the proportion of credit going to agnculture out of<br />

total loan were inversely rel<strong>at</strong>ed in both the regions. Further. the 110\\·<br />

of agricultural credit \\'as largely governed by the coll<strong>at</strong>eral sccurlt\<br />

(either l<strong>and</strong> or gold). Not surpnsingl~', larger the proportion of total<br />

advance <strong>for</strong> agricultural credit. more prominent \\'8S the colla tcral<br />

based lending.


These two findings had an impact on credit 10 the pn()rlt\<br />

sector. in general, <strong>and</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong>, in partlcular. as a proportl()11 ot<br />

(olal bank deposits. In the backward reglLln. the pmportllln ot pnurll \<br />

sector to lOtal deposits declined from 81.56 per cent 1I1 I q'Jl-l.ql) t(J<br />

72.35 per cent in 2000-01. In contrast, the same in the advanced<br />

region increased from 85.55 per cent to 116.70 per cent during the<br />

same period. Agricultural credit as proportion to total deposits<br />

declined from 27.04 per cent in 1998-99 to 23.15 pel' cent in 2000-01<br />

<strong>for</strong> the advanced region. A marginal Improvement of the same over the<br />

initial 39.10 per cent was observed Il1 the backward region during the<br />

same period. The policy of coll<strong>at</strong>eral based lending <strong>and</strong> expc'cted<br />

interest income on advances could be <strong>at</strong>tributed to these situ<strong>at</strong>ions.<br />

Factors Detennining the Access to <strong>Institutional</strong> Credit<br />

Empirical studies reveal th<strong>at</strong> the beneficiaries of rural credit extension<br />

policies <strong>and</strong> programmes were the rural well-to-do <strong>and</strong> not poor<br />

farmers (Rao 1975; Lipton 1976; Adams <strong>and</strong> Vogel 1986). Uther<br />

studies confirm this trend. These studies suggest th<strong>at</strong> only a small<br />

proportion of the total cultiv<strong>at</strong>ors in rural areas obtain loans from<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal financial institutions. Further, a small group among those<br />

with access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit monopolIsed the lIon's share of the net<br />

volume of credit disbursed (Lele 1981 ; Gonzalez-Vega 1984; Bra\'Cman<br />

<strong>and</strong> Guasch 1986; Egger 1986). Sarap (1990) argues th<strong>at</strong> a large gap<br />

existed between, on the one h<strong>and</strong>, the overall supply of credit to small<br />

<strong>and</strong> marginal farmers, <strong>and</strong> on the other, their need <strong>for</strong> thIS.<br />

Factors determining the access to institutional credit b\' tilt'<br />

farm household were analysed in the SIxth chapter. As dIscussed. the<br />

credit transaction depended not just on the need of the' f~'rm'T t()r "


loan, <strong>and</strong> the rel<strong>at</strong>ed need to meet the conditions gOH'fning 1 his<br />

borrowing, but also the lender's willingness to extend credit. In l his<br />

context, farmers' access to institutional credit was estim<strong>at</strong>ed b,· using<br />

the Probit Model where the dependent variable was a dichotomous<br />

variable indic<strong>at</strong>ing whether a particular farm household had access to<br />

credit or not. The assumption made by the Probit Model \\·as th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

probability of borrowing from the <strong>for</strong>mal sector sources was<br />

determined completely by the bank which decided whether a farm<br />

household would get a loan or not. This model also assumed th<strong>at</strong> all<br />

cultiv<strong>at</strong>ing households dem<strong>and</strong>ed institutional credit <strong>at</strong> the existing<br />

interest r<strong>at</strong>e, <strong>and</strong> th<strong>at</strong> the <strong>for</strong>mal sector was the cheapest source of<br />

credit <strong>for</strong> farmer borrowers.<br />

The analysis <strong>at</strong> the household level shows th<strong>at</strong> the farm <strong>and</strong><br />

household characteristics like quality of l<strong>and</strong>, value of non-l<strong>and</strong><br />

assets, irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area <strong>and</strong> educ<strong>at</strong>ional qualific<strong>at</strong>ions of the borrowers<br />

improve the prospects of a farm household's access to <strong>for</strong>mal loan,<br />

<strong>and</strong> hence, borrowing, The results also show th<strong>at</strong> the actual size of<br />

l<strong>and</strong>holding did not significantly influence the access, This finding<br />

contradicts the findings of some of the earlier studies th<strong>at</strong> larger the<br />

size of l<strong>and</strong> owned by the households, gre<strong>at</strong>er was the probabilitv of<br />

its access to the <strong>for</strong>mal sector (Kochar 1997; Swain 2002), The lower<br />

caste farmers (SCjST), <strong>and</strong> a farmer who had higher non-farm income<br />

as proportion to the total income were less likely to hm'e access to<br />

credit, as is evident from the neg<strong>at</strong>ive coefficient of these \'ariablcs,<br />

It is also evident from the sample of farm households of<br />

Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district th<strong>at</strong> even where farmers had access to <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

credit, the amount obtained \\·as inadequ<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong> their f(:qll1rements.


This necessit<strong>at</strong>ed borrowing from in<strong>for</strong>mal sources. This e\'ic!encl'<br />

supports the argument th<strong>at</strong> the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> agricultural credit fm<br />

exceeded its supply, In this context, it is discussed in chapter VI th<strong>at</strong><br />

in a financial situ<strong>at</strong>ion characterised by the absence of C1'edit<br />

r<strong>at</strong>ioning, the factors influencing the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit would<br />

obviously determine the quantum of credit supply, It is also argued<br />

th<strong>at</strong> where credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning (either in the <strong>for</strong>m of price or non-price)<br />

existed, the factors influencing the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit could not be<br />

considered as the ultim<strong>at</strong>e determinants of its supply. It is, there<strong>for</strong>e,<br />

to identify which of these factors - dem<strong>and</strong> or supply, accounted <strong>for</strong><br />

the flow of institutional credit, the determinants were estim<strong>at</strong>ed.<br />

Since the <strong>for</strong>mal lenders gave importance to coll<strong>at</strong>eral security<br />

<strong>and</strong> repayment capacity of the borrower, area under oper<strong>at</strong>ion (OA)<br />

<strong>and</strong> value of farm output (VAO) were considered as suppb;-side<br />

factors. The percentage of irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area to gross cropped area<br />

(PIAGCA), expenditure on farm inputs like fertiliser <strong>and</strong> pesticides<br />

(INEOFA), educ<strong>at</strong>ional qualific<strong>at</strong>ion (EDU) <strong>and</strong> caste of the borrower<br />

(CASTE) <strong>and</strong> the r<strong>at</strong>io of workers to family members (WFM) were<br />

specified as dem<strong>and</strong>-side factors. As elabor<strong>at</strong>ed in this chapter, access<br />

to <strong>for</strong>mal credit in the case of certain farming was not r<strong>and</strong>om. In<br />

order to correct this problem of selectivity bias, the Inverse Mills R<strong>at</strong>io<br />

(IMR) was calcul<strong>at</strong>ed from the above Probit equ<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> the same<br />

was introduced as an additional explan<strong>at</strong>ory variable in the equ<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

on the determinants of credit. The results show th<strong>at</strong> PIAGCA. SOU,<br />

WFM, EXPFP, INEOFA <strong>and</strong> VAO positively influenced the supph' of<br />

agricultural credit, whereas OA <strong>and</strong> CASTE adversely affected it.


Logit <strong>and</strong> Probit Models are useful if the qucstion is Wh"1 her or<br />

not there is access to credit. But they arc inappropri<strong>at</strong>e \\'hen 11 is<br />

important to measure the amount of credit obtained. The Tobil i\lllckl<br />

h<strong>and</strong>les censored dependent variables (continuous between some<br />

lower <strong>and</strong> possibly upper bound) better <strong>and</strong>, hence, is supnior to<br />

Logit <strong>and</strong> Probit. The Tobit results again confirm th<strong>at</strong> PIAC'CA. VAO.<br />

EXPFP, <strong>and</strong> CASTE were important variables in determining the<br />

amount of credit obtained.<br />

Credit Gap <strong>and</strong> Coping Str<strong>at</strong>egies<br />

Several factors were, thus, inhibiting agricultural borrO\\'ers, in<br />

general, <strong>and</strong> marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers in particular, from obtaining<br />

production credit. It is observed th<strong>at</strong> the credIt r<strong>at</strong>ioning went in<br />

favour of large size farmers. Interestingly, not only a small fractIOn of<br />

total number of farmers had access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit, but some of them<br />

also reported th<strong>at</strong> they faced many problems while obtaining the<br />

credit. Some of these problems also contributed to the higher<br />

transaction costs <strong>and</strong> delay in the disbursement of credit. In this<br />

context, the quality of credit delivery system, the extent of credit-gap,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the coping str<strong>at</strong>egy adopted by the farmers in the study area were<br />

analysed in the seventh chapter.<br />

The problems faced by the farmers be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>and</strong> after obtaining<br />

loans have been used as indic<strong>at</strong>ors on the quality of the eXIsting credit<br />

delivery system. Important problems were complic<strong>at</strong>ed procedures,<br />

lack of previous experience, distant loc<strong>at</strong>ion of the bank <strong>and</strong> untlmcl\<br />

<strong>and</strong> inadequ<strong>at</strong>e loan. Of the 200 sample farmers, 56.5 per cem st<strong>at</strong>cd<br />

th<strong>at</strong> bank procedures were complex, 69.5 per ccnt felt t:1,,1 the


disbursl'd loan amount was inadequ<strong>at</strong>l' <strong>and</strong> 49 pl'r cent \\"l'rL' of the<br />

view thal loans were untimely.<br />

More importantly, the quality of <strong>for</strong>mal credit dC'liven system<br />

was particularly poor in the case of marginal <strong>and</strong> small farmers.<br />

Bribing the bank officIals was a widespread problem in the case of<br />

marginal farmers. A general feeling among the borrowers was th<strong>at</strong><br />

"bribing is the only means to obtain a loan <strong>for</strong> allied agricultural<br />

activities under the subsidy <strong>and</strong>/ or poverty allevi<strong>at</strong>ion sehemes". The<br />

evidence shows th<strong>at</strong> the creditworthiness, viability of the proposal.<br />

<strong>and</strong> the amount of cash disbursed were positively rel<strong>at</strong>ed with the<br />

amount of bribe, while the time taken to get the loan sanctioned was<br />

neg<strong>at</strong>ively rel<strong>at</strong>ed.<br />

Given th<strong>at</strong> the above would increase the transaction costs<br />

(Adams <strong>and</strong> Nehman 1979; Sarap 1990J., the borrowing costs incurred<br />

by farmers in obtaining short-term loans were worked out. The<br />

evidence shows th<strong>at</strong> the average transaction cost as a proportion to<br />

average borrowing cost was inversely rel<strong>at</strong>ed with the size of the loan,<br />

whereas, the average interest costs as a percentage of average<br />

borrowing costs was positively rel<strong>at</strong>ed with the size of the loan.<br />

The flow of <strong>for</strong>mal credit was insufficient to meet the production<br />

costs of peasant farmers engaged in culti\'<strong>at</strong>ion. To meet the<br />

remaining cost they turned either to self-<strong>finance</strong> or to borrowing from<br />

the in<strong>for</strong>mal market or both or remained s<strong>at</strong>isfied with poo;'<br />

investment. It was in this context, th<strong>at</strong> the credit-gap had b(TI1<br />

estim<strong>at</strong>ed by size classes of l<strong>and</strong>holdings within <strong>and</strong> across the<br />

regIOns.


The term "credit-gap" has been defined as the un met credit<br />

needs of potential borrowers from either <strong>for</strong>mal or in<strong>for</strong>mal or fmm<br />

both the sources with their respective terms <strong>and</strong> conditions. H()\\T\·"J".<br />

the actual <strong>and</strong> rel<strong>at</strong>ive credit-gap per acre of gross cropped arca has<br />

been worked out to assess the magnitude of shortage of funds to meet<br />

the cost of production, Given tbe self-<strong>finance</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal credit the<br />

amount of in<strong>for</strong>mal credit taken per acre of gross cropped area \\'as<br />

termed as "actual credit-gap", wbereas, tbe differential amount<br />

between the maximum <strong>and</strong> the actual paid-out cost per acre of gross<br />

cropped area was defined as "rel<strong>at</strong>ive credit-gap". Since ll1CITaSe 111<br />

investment on crop production increased the level of production,<br />

ceteris paribus (viz" crop failure, clim<strong>at</strong>ic condition, pnces of<br />

agricultural product <strong>and</strong> so on), all c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers \\'ould have<br />

been interested to invest to the extent of maximum paid-out cost per<br />

acre in the respective regions provided the required amount of credit<br />

was available to them, Thus, the l<strong>at</strong>ter method assumed to be more<br />

important in the sense th<strong>at</strong> it explained the situ<strong>at</strong>ion, where the<br />

peasant farmer remained s<strong>at</strong>isfied with poor investment due to lack of<br />

availability of credit from either or both the sources.<br />

It is noticed th<strong>at</strong> both actual <strong>and</strong> rel<strong>at</strong>ive credit-gaps were more<br />

111 the advanced region as compared to the backward region <strong>for</strong> all<br />

c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers, Even if the obtained amount of <strong>for</strong>mal credit per<br />

acre of gross cropped area <strong>and</strong> self-<strong>finance</strong> capacity was more in the<br />

advanced region, still the extent of credit-gap \\'as more. Gi\Tn the<br />

self-<strong>finance</strong>, the higher credit-gap in the advanced region was<br />

<strong>at</strong>tributed to the higher cost of production. This indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

available scale of <strong>finance</strong> was inadequ<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> well below the actual<br />

cost of production,


As a coping str<strong>at</strong>eg:.·. farmers turned to in<strong>for</strong>mal credit market<br />

with some terms <strong>and</strong> conditions. It was analysed th<strong>at</strong> these contracts<br />

could be in terms of either coll<strong>at</strong>eral or coll<strong>at</strong>eral substltutcs or<br />

personal security or third party guarantor. The composition of<br />

borrowing against different types of coll<strong>at</strong>eral sho\\'s th<strong>at</strong> the quality of<br />

coll<strong>at</strong>eral increased with the rise in the st<strong>at</strong>us of borrowers. The terms<br />

<strong>and</strong> conditions of loan contract became unfavourable \\'ith the decline<br />

in the quality of coll<strong>at</strong>eral assets provided by the borrowers, <strong>and</strong> in<br />

turn, the extent of exploit<strong>at</strong>ion.<br />

Conclusions<br />

The overall conclusions emerging from the analysis of credit flow to<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> both <strong>at</strong> the <strong>macro</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>micro</strong> <strong>levels</strong> are briefly provided<br />

below.<br />

• The analysis <strong>at</strong> the all India level shows th<strong>at</strong> the proportion of<br />

credit going to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector to net bank credit has been<br />

declining from 1991. A similar situ<strong>at</strong>ion was also found across the<br />

bank groups.<br />

• The credit in both absolute <strong>and</strong> real terms grew <strong>at</strong> much faster r<strong>at</strong>e<br />

during the period 1981-91 as compared to the period 1992-2000,<br />

in general, <strong>and</strong> across the financial institutions. in particular.<br />

• Despite the fix<strong>at</strong>ion of lending target, clubbing of direct <strong>and</strong><br />

indirect <strong>finance</strong>s, deregul<strong>at</strong>ion of interest r<strong>at</strong>es, reduction in the<br />

number of slabs in lending r<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong> simplific<strong>at</strong>ion of credit<br />

delivery system, the banks could not achieve the targeted Clmoun t<br />

in the case of agricultural lending <strong>at</strong> the all India level. Although


the consensus was th<strong>at</strong> the credit to agriculturc should be stepped<br />

up, the banks did not find the agricultural sector profitable <strong>for</strong><br />

deploying larger proportion of their loanable funds.<br />

• The st<strong>at</strong>e-wise p<strong>at</strong>tern ll1 the agricultural lending shows th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

proportion of agricultural credit from net bank credit declined in<br />

most of the st<strong>at</strong>es during 1981-90. However, this decline was<br />

common <strong>for</strong> all the st<strong>at</strong>es during 1990s. The growth r<strong>at</strong>e of<br />

agricultural credit was higher during the pre-re<strong>for</strong>m period as<br />

compared to th<strong>at</strong> after the post-1991 period in most of the st<strong>at</strong>es.<br />

The growth r<strong>at</strong>e was found to be uneven during the sub-periods as<br />

well as across the st<strong>at</strong>es.<br />

• The distribution of loan accounts by size-class of l<strong>and</strong>holdings <strong>at</strong><br />

the all India <strong>and</strong> St<strong>at</strong>e <strong>levels</strong> shows th<strong>at</strong> better-off farmers had<br />

improved access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit as compared to small <strong>and</strong><br />

marginal farmers. The low percentage of farmers accessing <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

credit with more loan amount per account in most of the st<strong>at</strong>es<br />

shows a concentr<strong>at</strong>ion of <strong>for</strong>mal loans in favour of a particular<br />

group of borrowers. This also indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> bankers adopted both<br />

price <strong>and</strong> non-price credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning technique in the borrower<br />

selection <strong>and</strong> fIx<strong>at</strong>ion of credit amount.<br />

• At the st<strong>at</strong>e level, irrig<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> banking facility were two important<br />

factors th<strong>at</strong> determined the supply of credit per hectare of gross<br />

napped area.<br />

• The analysis on purpose-\\'Jse flo\\" of credit <strong>at</strong> the bank-branch 1e\"C1<br />

in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i district reveals th<strong>at</strong> bankers were giving preference \u


lend <strong>for</strong> non-agricultural activilies. The analysis


poor quality of the credit deliver.' system made the institutional<br />

~' ~ -<br />

credit expensive <strong>for</strong> the small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers.<br />

• The poor quality of l<strong>and</strong>, illiteracy <strong>and</strong> lower caste st<strong>at</strong>us had an<br />

adverse effect on the access of agricultural borrowers to <strong>for</strong>mal<br />

credit institutions. However, the value of non-l<strong>and</strong> assets <strong>and</strong> area<br />

under irrig<strong>at</strong>ion improved the probability of farmer's access to<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal sector.<br />

• Irrig<strong>at</strong>ed area, value of agricultural output, expenditure on farm<br />

inputs <strong>and</strong> caste were important variables th<strong>at</strong> determined the<br />

amount of credit obtained.<br />

• The credit-gap was found to be higher in the advanced region due<br />

to higher cost of production. The magnitude of credit-gap was<br />

higher among small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers.<br />

Implic<strong>at</strong>ions of the Study <strong>for</strong> Policy <strong>and</strong> Theory<br />

The analysis carried out in the study has the following implic<strong>at</strong>ions <strong>for</strong><br />

policy <strong>and</strong> theory.<br />

(a) It is noticed from the all India level analysis th<strong>at</strong> an increase in the<br />

lending r<strong>at</strong>e reduces the supply of agricultural credit. This result is<br />

quite contradictory to the theory, which shows the positi\"(~<br />

associ<strong>at</strong>ion between interest r<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> the supply of credit.<br />

There<strong>for</strong>e, increasing lending r<strong>at</strong>e may not be an important means<br />

to increase the supply of agricultural credit.


It is argued th<strong>at</strong> increasing interest r<strong>at</strong>e or coll<strong>at</strong>eral reqUIrement<br />

mcreases the risk of the bank's loan portfolio bv either<br />

discouraging safer investor or by inducing borrowers to invest in<br />

riskier projects <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e, decreases the bank profit (Stiglitz<br />

<strong>and</strong> Weiss 1981; Besley 1994). A lender may thus be better off<br />

r<strong>at</strong>ioning access to credit <strong>at</strong> a lower interest r<strong>at</strong>e r<strong>at</strong>her than<br />

raising the interest r<strong>at</strong>e of agricultural credit.<br />

Elsewhere, it is also argued th<strong>at</strong> the borrowers were willing to pay<br />

higher interest r<strong>at</strong>es if they got adequ<strong>at</strong>e <strong>and</strong> timely loans<br />

(Rajasekhar <strong>and</strong> Vyasulu 1990; Gadgil 1994, 1997). But in our<br />

existing credit delivery system "th<strong>at</strong> is a big if'. The borrowers,<br />

willing to pay high interest r<strong>at</strong>e, may be less worried about<br />

repayment of the loan. In this context, given the asymmetric<br />

in<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion, Stiglitz <strong>and</strong> Weiss (1981) show th<strong>at</strong> a profit<br />

maximising bank will practice credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning <strong>and</strong> be reluctant to<br />

increase interest r<strong>at</strong>es in response to an excess dem<strong>and</strong>.<br />

(b) Our analysis shows the credit subsidy adversely affectmg the<br />

supply of agricultural credit. It is also noticed th<strong>at</strong> increasing<br />

lending r<strong>at</strong>e cannot be an appropri<strong>at</strong>e measure to reduce the credit<br />

subsidy since it also adversely affects the supply of agricultural<br />

credit. There<strong>for</strong>e, it can be suggested th<strong>at</strong> reduction in the cost of<br />

lending in terms of either financial cost or transaction cost or risk<br />

cost or by any combin<strong>at</strong>ions of these three should be the prime<br />

objective of the financial institutions to reduce the burden of credit<br />

subsidy. This can be made possible by better qualIty of credit<br />

delivery system (timely <strong>and</strong> adequ<strong>at</strong>e) <strong>and</strong> prompt repa\'ment of<br />

loans.


(c) The density of bank branches positively influence the suppl\' of<br />

<strong>for</strong>mal credit. The regression results show th<strong>at</strong> an increase in the<br />

rural bank branches by one per cent leads to 0.52 increase in the<br />

net bank credit <strong>at</strong> all India leveL This shows th<strong>at</strong> the polic.v of<br />

closing the loss-making bank branches is not really helpmg the<br />

cause of <strong>agriculture</strong>. Any further reduction in the number of bank<br />

branches may adversely effect the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> sector.<br />

Hence, if the rural bank branches are to be closed under<br />

profitability consider<strong>at</strong>ion, importance should be given to<br />

altern<strong>at</strong>ive mechanisms like mcreasmg the number of staff 111<br />

neighbouring bank branches, simplific<strong>at</strong>ion of procedures in loan<br />

sanctioned, computeris<strong>at</strong>ion of bank branches, <strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion of<br />

larmers' organis<strong>at</strong>ions, self-help groups <strong>and</strong> so on.<br />

(d) The decline in the proportion of agricultural credit to net bank<br />

credit has been alarming. The policy, in this context, should be a<br />

stipul<strong>at</strong>ion of linking credit with deposits r<strong>at</strong>her than stipul<strong>at</strong>ing<br />

the floor level as a proportion of net bank credit. This can also be<br />

supported by the findings of the bank branch level analysis.<br />

(e) As of now the practice is to monitor the credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> in<br />

terms of the proportion of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> in total net bank<br />

credit. Our analysis shows th<strong>at</strong> this may not reflect the true<br />

picture in so far as credit flow to <strong>agriculture</strong> is concerned. Hence,<br />

given the positive dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> institutional credit, specific target<br />

should be made in terms of proportion of credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> to<br />

total bank deposits.


(I) It is found th<strong>at</strong> the security value taken b\' thc bankcrs was much<br />

more than the loan amount given to thc farmers. A polin' change<br />

should be made to ensure th<strong>at</strong> the loan sanctioned IS<br />

commensur<strong>at</strong>e with the value of security.<br />

(g) At the household level, a rel<strong>at</strong>ively high dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> credit was<br />

found with fairly large credit r<strong>at</strong>ioning. This implies th<strong>at</strong> there is<br />

need to develop credit programmes to support the credit needs of<br />

different c<strong>at</strong>egories of farmers, especially the marginal <strong>and</strong> small.<br />

Interestingly, the quality of l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the value of output arc<br />

significant determinants of access to credit <strong>and</strong> amount of loan<br />

obtained respectively r<strong>at</strong>her than the size of l<strong>and</strong>. This calls <strong>for</strong><br />

pollcy <strong>and</strong> programme support in the <strong>for</strong>m of w<strong>at</strong>ershed, irrig<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

development, etc., to improve the quality of l<strong>and</strong>.<br />

(h) In order to reduce the credit-gap problem, there should be<br />

rethinking on the scale of <strong>finance</strong>. Nevertheless, a separ<strong>at</strong>e scale of<br />

<strong>finance</strong> should be fixed <strong>for</strong> each service area of the concerned bank<br />

since the cost of production varies across the regions.<br />

Banking sector re<strong>for</strong>ms were introduced to improve the quality<br />

<strong>and</strong> viability of the credit delivery system, so th<strong>at</strong> the credit flow to thc<br />

hitherto neglected sectors such as agricultural would bc stepped up.<br />

This study on institutional <strong>finance</strong> to <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>at</strong> both <strong>macro</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>micro</strong> <strong>levels</strong> found th<strong>at</strong> credit to <strong>agriculture</strong> had in fact declined <strong>and</strong><br />

the better-off farmers have not been adversely affected by this. Credil<br />

r<strong>at</strong>ioning is widely practised by bankers, <strong>and</strong> the small <strong>and</strong> marginal<br />

farmers have been worse hit. The small <strong>and</strong> marginal farmers, unable<br />

to obtain timely <strong>and</strong> adequ<strong>at</strong>e <strong>for</strong>mal credit, turn to in<strong>for</strong>mal sourn's.


<strong>and</strong>, in the process, are being subjected to an exploit<strong>at</strong>ion in the interlinked<br />

credit markets. The access to institutional credit <strong>for</strong> small <strong>and</strong><br />

marginal farmers, there<strong>for</strong>e, continues to be an outst<strong>and</strong>ing Issue<br />

notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing (or due to?) the recent banking sector re<strong>for</strong>ms.


231<br />

REFERENCES<br />

Adams, D. W. <strong>and</strong> D. H. Graham (1981). A Critique of Traditional<br />

Agricultural Credit Projects <strong>and</strong> Policies. JOimwl of Development<br />

Economics, VIII (3): 347-66.<br />

Adams, D. W. <strong>and</strong> G. 1. Nehman (1979). Borrowing Cost <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> Rural Credit. The Journal of Development Studies,<br />

XV (2): 165-76.<br />

Adams, D. W. <strong>and</strong> J. L. Tommy (1974). Financing Small Farmers: The<br />

Brazilian Experience 1965-69. Agricultural Finance Review,<br />

XXXV, 36-41.<br />

Adams, D. W. <strong>and</strong> Robert C. Vogel (1986). Rural Financial Markets in<br />

Low-Income Countries: Recent Controversies <strong>and</strong> Lessons.<br />

World Development, XIV (4): 477 - 87.<br />

Anderson, D. <strong>and</strong> Farida Khamb<strong>at</strong>a (1985). Financing Small-Scale<br />

Industry <strong>and</strong> Agriculture in Developing Countries: The Merits<br />

<strong>and</strong> Limit<strong>at</strong>ions of "Commercial" Policies. Economic Development<br />

<strong>and</strong> Cultural Change, XXXIII (2): 349-71.<br />

Araujo, Paulo F.e. <strong>and</strong> Richard L. Meyer (1978). Agricultural Credit<br />

Policy in Brazil: Objectives <strong>and</strong> Results. Savings <strong>and</strong><br />

Development, II, 169-94.<br />

Aron, 1. (1981). Modernis<strong>at</strong>ion of Agriculture in Developing Countries:<br />

Resources, Potentials <strong>and</strong> Problems. Binghamton: John Wiley<br />

<strong>and</strong> Sons.<br />

Aryeetey, Ernest (1996). Rural Finance in Africa: <strong>Institutional</strong><br />

Development <strong>and</strong> Access the Poor. Annual World Bank<br />

Conference on Development Economics, The World Bank.<br />

Bardhan, P. (1984). L<strong>and</strong>, Labour, <strong>and</strong> Rural Poverty: Essays 111<br />

Development Economics. Delhi: Ox<strong>for</strong>d University Press<br />

Bardhan, P. (ed.) (1989). The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institurions,<br />

Ox<strong>for</strong>d: Clarendon Press


Bardhan, P. <strong>and</strong> A. Rudra (1978). Interlinkage of L<strong>and</strong>, Labour <strong>and</strong><br />

Credit Rel<strong>at</strong>ions: An <strong>Analysis</strong> of Village Survey d<strong>at</strong>a in East<br />

India. Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, XIll (7): 367-84.<br />

Bardhan, P. K. (1984). L<strong>and</strong>, Labour <strong>and</strong> Rural Poverty. New York:<br />

Columbia University Press.<br />

Basu, K. (1983). The Emergence of Isol<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> Interlinkage in Rural<br />

Markets. Ox<strong>for</strong>d Economic Papers, XXXV (2): 262-80.<br />

Basu, K. (1986). Market, Power <strong>and</strong> Social Norms. Economic alld<br />

Political Weekly, XXI (43): 1893-6.<br />

Basu, K. (1989). Rural Credit Markets: The Structure of Interest<br />

R<strong>at</strong>es, Exploit<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> Efficiency. In P.K. Bardhan (ed.). The<br />

Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions. Ox<strong>for</strong>d: Clarendon<br />

Press.<br />

tlasu, Santanu (1 SJSJ7). Why <strong>Institutional</strong> Credit Agencies are<br />

Reluctant to Lend to the Rural Poor: A Theoretical <strong>Analysis</strong> of<br />

the Indian Credit Market. World Development, XXV (2): 267-80.<br />

Bedbak, H. (1986). <strong>Institutional</strong> Financing <strong>for</strong> Priority Sectors: An<br />

Empirical Assessment of Delay <strong>and</strong> <strong>Analysis</strong> of Attitudes of<br />

Agencies Towards Loanees. Indian Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ive Review, XXIV<br />

(1): 65-76.<br />

Bell, Clive (1990). Interactions between <strong>Institutional</strong> <strong>and</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal<br />

Credit Agencies in Rural India. The World Bank Economic<br />

Review, IV (3): 297-327.<br />

BesIey, Timothy (1994). How do Market Failures Justify Interventions<br />

in Rural Credit Markets? The World Bank Research Observer, IX<br />

(1): 27-47.<br />

Bhaduri, A. (1977). On the Form<strong>at</strong>ion of Usurious Interest R<strong>at</strong>es 111<br />

Backward Agriculture. Cambridge Journal of Ecollomics, I (4).<br />

Binswanger, Hans P. <strong>and</strong> M.R. Rosenz\\"ieg (1986). Behavioural <strong>and</strong><br />

M<strong>at</strong>erial Determinants of Production Rel<strong>at</strong>ion in Agriculture.<br />

Journal of Development Studies, XXXI! (3): 503-39.<br />

232


233<br />

Binswanger, Hans P. <strong>and</strong> Donald A. Sillers (1983). Risk A\'ersion <strong>and</strong><br />

Credit Constraints in Farmers' DeCIsion-Making: A<br />

Reinterpret<strong>at</strong>ion. Journal of Development Studies, XXII (1): 5-21.<br />

Binswanger, Hans P. <strong>and</strong> Kalus Deininger (1997).<br />

Agricultural <strong>and</strong> Agrarian Policies In Developing<br />

Joumal of Economic Liter<strong>at</strong>ure, XXXV (4): 1958-2005.<br />

Explaining<br />

Countncs.<br />

Binswanger, Hans P. <strong>and</strong> Shahidur R. Kh<strong>and</strong>ker (1995). The Impact of<br />

Formal Finance on the Rural Economy of India. Journal of<br />

Development Studies, XXXIl (2). 234-62,<br />

Bishnoi, T, R. (1991), Policy Constraints <strong>and</strong> Banks' Profitability:<br />

Impact of Priority Sector Credit, Intemauonal Journal of<br />

Development Banking, IX (1): 39-46.<br />

Bottomley, A, (1975). Interest R<strong>at</strong>e Determin<strong>at</strong>ion in Underdeveloped<br />

Rural Areas, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 57 (2):<br />

279-91.<br />

Braveman, A. <strong>and</strong> J. L. Guasch (1986). Rural Credit Markets <strong>and</strong><br />

Institutions in Developing Countries: Lessons <strong>for</strong> Policy <strong>Analysis</strong><br />

from Practice <strong>and</strong> Modern Theory. World Development, XIV (10):<br />

1253-67.<br />

Braveman, A. <strong>and</strong> T.N, Srinivasan (1981). Credit <strong>and</strong> Sharecropping in<br />

Agrarian Societies, Journal of Development Economics, IX (3):<br />

289-312,<br />

Braverman, A. <strong>and</strong> J.L. Guasch (1989). Rural Credit in Developing<br />

Countries. PPR, Working Paper, No, 219. Washington DC: The<br />

World Bank.<br />

Chaudhuri, S. (1993), Problems of <strong>Institutional</strong> Credit <strong>and</strong> Small<br />

Farmers: A Study of Two selected VIllages of West Bengal.<br />

Unpublished.<br />

Chaudhuri, Sarbajit <strong>and</strong> Manas Ranjan Gupta (1996). Dela\'ed Formal<br />

Credit, Bribing <strong>and</strong> the In<strong>for</strong>mal Credit Market in Agriculture: A<br />

Theoretical <strong>Analysis</strong>. Journal of Development Economics, 51:<br />

433-49.


Cho, Yoon Je (1986). Inefficiencies from Financial Liberalis<strong>at</strong>ion in the<br />

Absence of Well-Functioning Equity Markets. Joumal of Money.<br />

Credit <strong>and</strong> Banking, IX (I): 39-46.<br />

D<strong>and</strong>ekar, V. M. <strong>and</strong> F. K. Wadia (1989). Development of <strong>Institutional</strong><br />

Finance <strong>for</strong> Agriculture in India. Joumal of Indian School of<br />

Political Economy, I (2): 167-211.<br />

Das, J. (1962). Final Report of L<strong>and</strong> Revenue Settlement in Kalah<strong>and</strong>i<br />

District, Ex-St<strong>at</strong>e Khalsa, 1945-46. Bhubaneswar: Government<br />

of Orissa.<br />

Desai, Bhup<strong>at</strong> M. (1993). Rural Banking: Misdirected Policy Changes.<br />

Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, XXVIlI (18): 2868 - 70.<br />

Desai, Bhup<strong>at</strong> M. <strong>and</strong> N. V. Namboodiri (1 992). Per<strong>for</strong>mance of<br />

<strong>Institutional</strong> Finance <strong>for</strong> Agricultural Development. Economic<br />

<strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, XXVII (51 <strong>and</strong> 52): A-190 - A-196.<br />

Donald, Gordon (1976). Credit <strong>for</strong> Small Farmers in Developing<br />

Countries. Boulder, CU: Westview Press.<br />

E<strong>at</strong>on, J. <strong>and</strong> M. Gersovitz (1981). Debt with Potential RepUdi<strong>at</strong>ion:<br />

Theoretical <strong>and</strong> Empirical <strong>Analysis</strong>. Review of Economic Studies,<br />

XLVIII (2): 289-310.<br />

Egger, P. (1986). Banking <strong>for</strong> the Rural Poor: Lessons from Some<br />

Innov<strong>at</strong>ive Saving <strong>and</strong> Credit Schemes. Intem<strong>at</strong>ional Labour<br />

Review, 125 (4): 447-62.<br />

Fried, Joel <strong>and</strong> Peter Howitt (1980). Credit R<strong>at</strong>ioning <strong>and</strong> Implicit<br />

Contract Theory. Journal of Money Credit <strong>and</strong> Banking, XlII (2):<br />

471-87.<br />

Fry, M. (1988). Money, Interest <strong>and</strong> Banking in Economic Development.<br />

Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.<br />

Fry, Maxwell J. (1979). The Cost of Financial Repression in Turkev.<br />

Savings <strong>and</strong> Development, 11[, 127-35.<br />

Gadgil, M.V. (1986). Agricultural Credit m India: A Review of<br />

Per<strong>for</strong>mance <strong>and</strong> Policies. Indian Joumal of Agnculluml<br />

Economics, XLI (3): 282 - 309.<br />

234


Gadgil, M.V. (1992). Future of <strong>Institutional</strong> Agricultural Crt'dit in<br />

India: Likely Impact of Narasimham <strong>and</strong> Khusro Commit tee<br />

Reports. Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 47(2): 255-05.<br />

Gadgil, M.V. (1994). Formal Agricultural Credit SYstem in India:<br />

Shape of Things to Come. Indian Journal of Agricultural<br />

Economics, XLIX (3): 476-90.<br />

Gadgil, M.V. (1997). N<strong>at</strong>ional Bank <strong>for</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural<br />

Development, Promise <strong>and</strong> Per<strong>for</strong>mance, 1982-83 to 1995-96.<br />

Journal of Indian School of Political Economy, IX (2): 207-65.<br />

Gangopadhyay, S. (1997). Some Issues in Interlinked Agrarian<br />

Markets. In Kaushik Basu (ed.), Agrarian Questions. New Delhi:<br />

Ox<strong>for</strong>d University Press.<br />

Gangopadhyay, S. <strong>and</strong> Kunal Sengupta (1987). Small Farmers, Money<br />

Lenders <strong>and</strong> Trading Activity. Ox<strong>for</strong>d Economic Papers, 39 (2):<br />

333-342.<br />

George, P.T., D. Namasivayam <strong>and</strong> G. Ramach<strong>and</strong>raiah (J 985). Rural<br />

Credit <strong>and</strong> Farmer's Borrowing Cost: A Case Study. Prajnan,<br />

XIV (3): 190-201.<br />

Gh<strong>at</strong>ak, S. (1977). Rural Credit <strong>and</strong> the Cost of Borrowing: Interst<strong>at</strong>e<br />

Vari<strong>at</strong>ions in India. Journal of Development Studies, XIII (2):<br />

102-24.<br />

Gh<strong>at</strong>ak, S. (1983). On Interregional Vari<strong>at</strong>ions in Rural Interest R<strong>at</strong>es<br />

in India. Journal of Development Areas, XVIII (1): 21-34.<br />

Gibson, He<strong>at</strong>her D. <strong>and</strong> Euclid Taskal<strong>at</strong>os (1994). The Scope <strong>and</strong><br />

Limits of Financial Liberalis<strong>at</strong>ion in Developing Countries: A<br />

Critical Survey. Journal of Development Studies, XXX (3): 578-<br />

628.<br />

Gonzalez-Vega, Claudio (1984). Credit R<strong>at</strong>ioning Behaviour of<br />

Agricultural Lenders: The Iron Law of Interest-R<strong>at</strong>e Restriction.<br />

In Dale W. Adams, Douglas H. Graham <strong>and</strong> J. D. Von Pischke<br />

(eds.), Undermining Rural Development with Cheap Credit.<br />

Colorado, US: Westview Press.<br />

Government of Orissa (1995-96). Orissa Agricultural St<strong>at</strong>istiCS.<br />

Bhubaneswar: Director<strong>at</strong>e of Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Food Production.<br />

235


Government of Orissa (1996). St<strong>at</strong>istical Abstract of Orissa.<br />

Bhubaneswar: Director<strong>at</strong>e of Economics <strong>and</strong> St<strong>at</strong>istics.<br />

Government of Orissa (1996-97). Orissa Agricultural St<strong>at</strong>istics.<br />

Bhubaneswar: Director<strong>at</strong>e of Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Food Production.<br />

Government of Orissa (1997). District St<strong>at</strong>istical H<strong>and</strong>book 1997,<br />

Kalah<strong>and</strong>i. Bhubaneswar: Director<strong>at</strong>e of Economics <strong>and</strong><br />

St<strong>at</strong>istics.<br />

Government of Orissa (1997-98). Orissa Agricultural St<strong>at</strong>istics.<br />

Bhubaneswar: Director<strong>at</strong>e of Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Food ProductlOn.<br />

Government of Orissa (1998-99). Orissa Agricultural Sl<strong>at</strong>istics.<br />

Bhubaneswar: Director<strong>at</strong>e of Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Food Production.<br />

Government of Orissa (1999-2000). Orissa Agricultural St<strong>at</strong>istics.<br />

Bhubaneswar: Director<strong>at</strong>e of Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Food Production.<br />

Government of Orissa (2000-2001). Economic Survey. Bhubaneswar:<br />

Director<strong>at</strong>e of Economics <strong>and</strong> St<strong>at</strong>istics, Planning <strong>and</strong> Coordin<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

Department, Government of Orissa.<br />

Gupta, R. V. (Chairman) (1998). Report of the High-Level Committee 011<br />

Agricultural Credit through Commercial Banks. Bombay: Reserve<br />

Bank of India.<br />

Hashuliza, A.K. <strong>and</strong> J.G. Kydd (1996). Determinants of Bank Credit<br />

Access <strong>for</strong> Smallholder Farmers in Tanzania: A Discrimin<strong>at</strong>e<br />

<strong>Analysis</strong> Applic<strong>at</strong>ion. Savings <strong>and</strong> Development, XX (3): 285 -<br />

304.<br />

Heckman, J. J. (1979). Sample Selection Bias as a Specific<strong>at</strong>ion Error.<br />

Econometrica, XLVII (1): 153-61.<br />

Helf<strong>and</strong>, M. Steven (2001). The Distribution of Subsidised Agricultural<br />

Credit in Brazil: Do Interest Group M<strong>at</strong>ter? Development <strong>and</strong><br />

Change, XXXII (3): 465-90.<br />

Hoff. Karla <strong>and</strong> Joseph E. Stiglitz (1993). Imperfect In<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong><br />

Rural Credit Markets: Puzzles <strong>and</strong> Policy Perspectives. In Karla<br />

Hoff. A. Braverman <strong>and</strong> Joseph E. Stiglitz (cds.), The Economics<br />

of Rural Organis<strong>at</strong>ion: Theory, Practice <strong>and</strong> Policy. Ne\\' York:<br />

Ox<strong>for</strong>d University Press <strong>for</strong> the World Bank.<br />

236


Hulme, David <strong>and</strong> Paul Mosley (1996). Finance Against Pover1y, Vol. 1.<br />

London, UK: Routledge.<br />

Jafee, Dwight M. (1971). Credit R<strong>at</strong>ioning <strong>and</strong> the Commercial Loan<br />

Market. New York: John Wiley.<br />

Johnston, J. <strong>and</strong> J. Di Nardo (1997). Econometric Methods, (4tH<br />

edition). New York: McGraw Hill.<br />

Kahlon, A. S. (1991). Rural Overdues: Borrower's Angle. Economic <strong>and</strong><br />

Political Weekly, XXVI (5): 243 - 6.<br />

Kamajou, Francois (1980). Subsidised Interest R<strong>at</strong>es <strong>and</strong> Restricted<br />

Agricultural Credit in LDCs. Saving <strong>and</strong> Development, IV (2):<br />

123-36.<br />

K<strong>at</strong>ula, R. <strong>and</strong> Ashok Gul<strong>at</strong>i (1992). <strong>Institutional</strong> Credit <strong>for</strong><br />

Agriculture: Issues Rel<strong>at</strong>ed to Interest <strong>and</strong> Default Subsidy.<br />

Journai of indian School of PolItIcal &onomy, IV (4): 701-29.<br />

Khusro, A. M. (1989). A Review of the Agricultural Credit System m<br />

India: Report of the Agricultural Credit Review Committee.<br />

Bombay: Reserve Bank of India.<br />

Kochar, Anjini (1997). An Empirical Investig<strong>at</strong>ion of R<strong>at</strong>ioning<br />

Constraints in Rural Credit Market in India. Journal of<br />

Development Economics, LIII (2): 339-71.<br />

Kohli, Renu (1997). Directed Credit <strong>and</strong> Financial System. Economic<br />

<strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, XXXII (42): 2667-76.<br />

Kohli, Renu (1999). Rural Bank Branches <strong>and</strong> Financial Re<strong>for</strong>m.<br />

Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, XXXIV (3 <strong>and</strong> 4): 169 - 74.<br />

Ladman, Jerry R. (1984). Loan Transaction Costs, Credit R<strong>at</strong>ioning,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Market Structure: The Case of Bolivia. In Dale W. Adams,<br />

Douglas H. Graham <strong>and</strong> J. D. Von Pischke (eds.), Undermining<br />

Rural Development with Cheap Credit. Colorado, US: Westvie\,·<br />

Press.<br />

Ladman, Jerry R. <strong>and</strong> D. W. Adams (1978). The Rural Poor <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Recent Per<strong>for</strong>mance of Formal Rural Financial Markets in the<br />

Dominican Republic. Canadian Journal of Agncultural<br />

Economics, XXXVI (1): 43-50.<br />

237


238<br />

Ladman, Jerry R. <strong>and</strong> Ronald L. Tinnermeier (1981). The Political<br />

Economy of Agricultural Credit: The Case of Bolivia. American<br />

Journal of Agricultural Economics, LXIII (1): 66 - 72.<br />

Lele, U. (1981). Co-oper<strong>at</strong>ives <strong>and</strong> the Poor: A Compar<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

Perspective. World Development, IX (1): 55-72.<br />

Lipton, M. (1976). Agricultural Finance <strong>and</strong> Rural Credit In Poor<br />

Countries. World Development, IV (7): 543-53.<br />

McKinnon, R. 1. (1973). Money <strong>and</strong> Capital in Economic Development.<br />

Washington DC: The Brooking Institution.<br />

Mitra, K. Pradeep (1983). A Theory of Interlinked Rural Transaction.<br />

Journal of Public Economics, XX (2): 167 -9l.<br />

Morduch, J. (2000). The Micro Finance System. World Development,<br />

XXVllI (4): 617-29.<br />

Naastepad, C. W. M. (2001). The Macro Economic Effect of Directed<br />

Credit Policies: A Real-Financial CGE Evalu<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>for</strong> India.<br />

Development <strong>and</strong> Change, XXXII (3): 491-520.<br />

Narashimham, M. (Chairman) (1991). Report of the Committee on the<br />

Financial System. New Delhi: Ministry of Finance, Government<br />

of India.<br />

N<strong>at</strong>ional Bank <strong>for</strong> Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural Development (2001-02).<br />

Potential Linked Credit Plan, Kalah<strong>and</strong>i. Bhubaneswar:<br />

NABARD.<br />

Odedokun, M. O. (1996). Intern<strong>at</strong>ional Evidence on the Effects of<br />

Directed Credit Programmes on Efficiency of Resource Alloc<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

in Developing Countries: The Case of Development Bank<br />

Lendings. Journal of Development Economics, 48 (2): 449-60.<br />

P<strong>and</strong>it, B. L. (1991). The Growth <strong>and</strong> Structure of Savings in India: An<br />

Econometric <strong>Analysis</strong>. New Delhi: Ox<strong>for</strong>d University Press.<br />

Petrick, M. <strong>and</strong> L. L<strong>at</strong>rufee (2003). Credit Access <strong>and</strong> Borrowing Costs<br />

in Pol<strong>and</strong>'s Agricultural Credit Market: A Hedonic Pricillg<br />

Approach (D.P. No. 46). Munich: Institute of Agricultural<br />

Development in Central <strong>and</strong> Eastern Europe.


Pindyck, R. S. <strong>and</strong> D. L. Rubinfeld (1997). Econometric Models alld<br />

Economic Forecasts. Fourth Edition. New York: McGraw-Hill.<br />

Pl<strong>at</strong>teau, J. Ph <strong>and</strong> Anita Abraham (1987). An Inquiry into Quasi­<br />

Credit Constraints: The Role of Reciprocal Credit <strong>and</strong><br />

Interlinked Deals in Small Scale Fishing Communities. The<br />

Joumal oj Development Studies, XXIII (4): 461-90.<br />

Rajasekhar, D. <strong>and</strong> Vinod Vyasulu (1990). Rural Credit Delivery<br />

System: A Study in Pali District of Rajasthan. Economic <strong>and</strong><br />

Political Weekly, XXV (39): A-125-A-134.<br />

Rajasekhar, D. <strong>and</strong> Vinod Vyasulu (1991). The Half-Life of Credit:<br />

Stimul<strong>at</strong>ing Fund Flows in the Priority Sector, Economic <strong>and</strong><br />

Political Weekly, XXVI (39): A-135-A-143.<br />

Rajasekhar, D. <strong>and</strong> Vinod Vyasulu (1993). Managerial Changes, Rural<br />

Credit <strong>and</strong> Economic Development: A Study in Orissa, India.<br />

Savings <strong>and</strong> Development, XVII (2): 183-208.<br />

Ramach<strong>and</strong>ran, V. K. <strong>and</strong> Madhura Swamin<strong>at</strong>han (2001). Does<br />

InJormal Credit Provide Security? Rural Banking Policy in India.<br />

Geneva: Intern<strong>at</strong>ional Labour Office.<br />

Rangarajan, C. (1996). Rural India, The Role of Credit. Reserve Bank<br />

oj India Bulletin. Bombay: RBI.<br />

Rao, C.H.H. (1975). Technological Change <strong>and</strong> Distribution of Gains in<br />

Indian Agriculture, New Delhi: Macmillan.<br />

Rao, C.H.H. (1994). Issues Rel<strong>at</strong>ing to Irrig<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> Rural Credit in<br />

India. In G. S. Bhalla (ed.), Economic Liberalis<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> Indian<br />

Agriculture. New Delhi: Institute <strong>for</strong> Studies in Industrial<br />

Development.<br />

Rao, M.G., R.T. Sh<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> K.P. Kalirajan (1999). Convergence of<br />

Incomes across Indian St<strong>at</strong>es. Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly,<br />

XXXIV (21: 167-88.<br />

Ray, Devraj (1998). Development Economics. New Delhi: Ox<strong>for</strong>d<br />

University Press.<br />

239


Reddy, Y.V. (2001). Future of Rural Banking. In Raj Kapila (cd.),<br />

India's Banking <strong>and</strong> Financial Sectors in New Millell/llum. Ne\\"<br />

Delhi: Academic Found<strong>at</strong>ion.<br />

Reserve Bank of India (1987-88). Report on Trends <strong>and</strong> Progress of<br />

Banking in India. Bombay: RBI.<br />

Reserve Bank of India (1991-92). Report on Trends <strong>and</strong> Progress of<br />

Banking in India. Bombay: RBI.<br />

Reserve Bank of India (1992-93). Report on Trends <strong>and</strong> Progress of<br />

Banking in India. Mumbai: RBI.<br />

Reserve Bank of India (1993-94). Report on Currency <strong>and</strong> Finance,<br />

Volume -/. Mumbai: RBI.<br />

Reserve Bank of India (1994). RBI Bulletin. Mumbai: RBI.<br />

Reserve Bank of India (1995). Report on Currency <strong>and</strong> Finance, Vol. I.<br />

Mumbai: RBI.<br />

Reserve Bank of India (1996-97). Report on Currency <strong>and</strong> Finance. Vol.<br />

I. Mumbai: RBI.<br />

Reserve Bank of India (1997-98). Report on Trends <strong>and</strong> Progress of<br />

Banking in India. Mumbai: RBI.<br />

Reserve Bank of India (2000). Banking St<strong>at</strong>istics, Quarterly H<strong>and</strong>out.<br />

Mumbai: RBI.<br />

Reserve Bank of India (2001). H<strong>and</strong> Book of St<strong>at</strong>istics on Indian<br />

Economy. Mumbai: RBI.<br />

Rhyne, E. (1998). The Yin <strong>and</strong> Yang of Micro-Finance: Reaching the<br />

Poor <strong>and</strong> Sustainability. The Micro-banking Bulletin (2).<br />

Rudra, A. (1982). Indian Agriculture: Myth <strong>and</strong> Realities. Ne\\' Delhi:<br />

Allied Publishers.<br />

Sarap, K. (1990). Factors Affecting Small Farmers' Access to<br />

<strong>Institutional</strong> Credit in Rural Orissa, India. Development <strong>and</strong><br />

Change, XXI (2): 281-307.<br />

240


Sarap, K. (1991). Coll<strong>at</strong>eral <strong>and</strong> other Forms of Guarantee III Rural<br />

Credit Markets: Evidence from Eastern India. Indian Economic<br />

Review, XXVI (2): 167-88.<br />

Sarkar, Jay<strong>at</strong>i <strong>and</strong> Pradeep Agrawal (1997). Banking: The Challenges<br />

of Deregul<strong>at</strong>ion. In Kirit S Parikh (ed.), India Deve{opml?1l1<br />

Report. Delhi: Ox<strong>for</strong>d University Press.<br />

S<strong>at</strong>ish, P. <strong>and</strong> C.K. Gopalkrishna (1997). Viability of Rural Banking.<br />

Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, XXXII(42): 2711-6.<br />

S<strong>at</strong>ish, S. <strong>and</strong> K. K. Swamin<strong>at</strong>h (1989). Lending Cost <strong>and</strong> Margin,<br />

Agricultural Credit Review, Bombay, (Study IV). Mumbai:<br />

Reserve Bank of India.<br />

Schrieder, Gertrud Buchenrieder (2000). Improving Bankability of<br />

Small Farmers in Northern Vietnam. Savings <strong>and</strong> Development,<br />

XXIV (4): 385-402.<br />

Sen, A.K. (1975). Employment Technology <strong>and</strong> Development. Ox<strong>for</strong>d:<br />

Clarendon Press.<br />

Shajahan, K.M. (1998). Priority Sector Bank Lending, Some Important<br />

Issues. Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, XXXIII (42 <strong>and</strong> 43): 2749-<br />

56.<br />

Shajahan, K.M. (1999). Priority Sector Bank Lending: How Useful?<br />

Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, XXXIV (51): 3572-4.<br />

Shaw, E. K. (1973). Financial Deepening in Economic Development.<br />

New Delhi: Ox<strong>for</strong>d University Press.<br />

Shivamaggi, H.V. (2000). Re<strong>for</strong>ms in Rural Banking: Need <strong>for</strong> Bolder<br />

Approach. Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, XXXV (20): 1714-8.<br />

Shylendra, H .S. (1995). Lender Viability <strong>and</strong> Lender Behaviour: A<br />

Case Study of a Regional Rural Bank in South India. Saving <strong>and</strong><br />

Development, XIX (2): 231-42.<br />

Shylendra, H.S. (1996). <strong>Institutional</strong> Re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>and</strong> Rural Poor: A Stud\'<br />

on the Distributional Per<strong>for</strong>mance of Regional Rural Bank.<br />

Indian Journal oj Agricultural Economics, 51 (3): 301-14.<br />

2~1


242<br />

Singh, Surjeet (ed.) (1991). Rural Credit: Issues <strong>for</strong> the Nineties. Ne\\'<br />

Delhi: Ox<strong>for</strong>d lBH.<br />

St<strong>at</strong>e Bank of India (2000-01). Annual Credit Plan - 2000-2001.<br />

Kalah<strong>and</strong>i District (Orissa). Bhubanes\\'ar: St<strong>at</strong>e Bank of India.<br />

Local Head Office.<br />

Stiglitz, J. (1990). Peer Monitoring <strong>and</strong> Credit Markets. The World<br />

Bank Economic Review, IV (3): 351-66.<br />

Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1994). The Role of the St<strong>at</strong>e in the Financial<br />

Markets. In the Proceedings of the World Bank Annual<br />

Conference on Development Economics 1993. Washington DC:<br />

The World Bank.<br />

Stiglitz, Joseph E. <strong>and</strong> Andrew Weiss (1981). Credit R<strong>at</strong>ioning in<br />

Markets with Imperfect In<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion. American Economic Review.<br />

LXXI (3): 393-410.<br />

Swain, R. B. (2002). Credit R<strong>at</strong>ioning in Rural India.<br />

Economic Development, XXVII (2): 1-20.<br />

Journal of<br />

Swamin<strong>at</strong>han, Madhura (1991). Segment<strong>at</strong>ion, Coll<strong>at</strong>eral Under<br />

valu<strong>at</strong>ion, <strong>and</strong> the R<strong>at</strong>e of Interest in Agrarian Credit Markets:<br />

Some Evidence from Two Villages in South India. Cambridge<br />

Journal of Economics, XV (2): 161-78.<br />

Timberg, T. A. <strong>and</strong> C. V. Aiyar (1984). In<strong>for</strong>mal Credit Market in India.<br />

Economic Development <strong>and</strong> Cultural Change, XXXIII (1): 43-59.<br />

Vaessen, Jos (2001). Accessibility of Rural Credit in Northern<br />

Nicaragua: The Importance of Networks of In<strong>for</strong>m<strong>at</strong>ion <strong>and</strong><br />

Recommend<strong>at</strong>ion. Savings <strong>and</strong> Development, XXV (1): 5 - 31.<br />

Vogel, Robert C. (1977). The Effects of Subsidised Agricultural Credit 0/1<br />

the Distribution of Income in Costa Rica. Carbondale, IL:<br />

Department of Economics, Southern Illinois University<br />

(un published).<br />

Vogel, Robert C. <strong>and</strong> Donald W. Larson (1980). Limit<strong>at</strong>ions of<br />

Agricultural Credit Planning: The Case of Colombia, Savings<br />

<strong>and</strong> Development IV.


Von Pischke, J. D. <strong>and</strong> Dale W. Adams (1980). Fungibility <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Design <strong>and</strong> Evalu<strong>at</strong>ion of Agricultural Credit Projects. American<br />

Joumal of Agricultural Economics, LXII (4): 719 - 26.<br />

Von Pischke, J. D., Dale W. Adams <strong>and</strong> Gordon Donald (1983). Rural<br />

Financial Markets in Developing Countries: Their Use <strong>and</strong> Abuse.<br />

Baltimore, Maryl<strong>and</strong>: Johns Hopkins University Press.<br />

Vyasulu, Vinod <strong>and</strong> D. Rajasekhar (1991). Management of Rural<br />

Credit: Issues <strong>for</strong> 1990s. Intern<strong>at</strong>ional Joumal of Developmen t<br />

Banking, IX (1): 47-53.<br />

Vyasulu, Vinod <strong>and</strong> D. Rajasekhar (1993).<br />

Development: Managerial Re<strong>for</strong>ms in<br />

Development Policy Review, 11 (4): 393-412.<br />

Credit <strong>for</strong> Rural<br />

Indian Banks,<br />

Wiggins, S. <strong>and</strong> S. Rajendran (1987). Rural Banking in Southern Tamil<br />

Nadu: Per<strong>for</strong>mance <strong>and</strong> Management. (Final Research Repon).<br />

Department of Agricultural Economics <strong>and</strong> Management,<br />

University of Reading<br />

World Bank (1989). World Development Report. Washington, DC: The<br />

World Bank.<br />

Yaron, J., M.P. Benjamin <strong>and</strong> G. Piprek (1997). Rural Finance: Issues,<br />

Design, <strong>and</strong> Best Practices. Washington DC: The World Bank.<br />

Yaron, Jacob (1994). Wh<strong>at</strong> Makes Rural Finance Institutions<br />

Successful? The World Bank Research Observer, IX (1): 49-70.<br />

Yaron, Jacob, McDonald Benjamin <strong>and</strong> Stephanie Charitonenko<br />

(1998). Promoting Efficient Rural Financial Intermedi<strong>at</strong>ion. The<br />

World Bank Research Observer, XIII (2): 147-70.<br />

243

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!