07.04.2014 Views

Pass-Through Rates and the Price Effects of Mergers - Vanderbilt ...

Pass-Through Rates and the Price Effects of Mergers - Vanderbilt ...

Pass-Through Rates and the Price Effects of Mergers - Vanderbilt ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Pass</strong>-<strong>Through</strong> <strong>Rates</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Price</strong> <strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Mergers</strong><br />

Luke Froeb ∗ <strong>and</strong> Steven Tschantz †<br />

V<strong>and</strong>erbilt University<br />

Nashville, TN 37203<br />

Gregory J. Werden ‡<br />

U.S. Department <strong>of</strong> Justice<br />

Washington, DC 20530<br />

October 6, 2003<br />

Abstract<br />

We investigate <strong>the</strong> relationship in Bertr<strong>and</strong> oligopoly between <strong>the</strong><br />

price effects <strong>of</strong> mergers absent synergies <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> rates at which merger<br />

synergies are passed through to consumers in <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> lower prices.<br />

We find that <strong>the</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> conditions that cause a merger to result in<br />

large price increases absent synergies also cause <strong>the</strong> pass-through rate<br />

to be high. The low estimated pass-through rate <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> relatively<br />

large predicted merger effect, thus, likely were inconsistent in an important<br />

US merger case.<br />

JEL Classification: D43 - Oligopoly; L41 - Horizontal Anticompetitive<br />

Practices<br />

Keywords: pass-through; merger; efficiencies; antitrust<br />

∗ Owen Graduate School <strong>of</strong> Management, luke.froeb@v<strong>and</strong>erbilt.edu, corresponding author.<br />

After this paper was completed, Froeb was named Director <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Bureau <strong>of</strong> Economics,<br />

Federal Trade Commission. The views expressed here are those <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> authors<br />

<strong>and</strong> not those <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> FTC or its commissioners.<br />

† Department <strong>of</strong> Ma<strong>the</strong>matics, tschantz@math.v<strong>and</strong>erbilt.edu<br />

‡ gregory.werden@usdoj.gov. The views expressed in this paper are not purported to<br />

represent those <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> U.S. Department <strong>of</strong> Justice.


1 Introduction<br />

In static Bertr<strong>and</strong> oligopoly, we investigate <strong>the</strong> link between price increases<br />

from mergers absent synergies <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> pass through to consumers <strong>of</strong> marginal<br />

cost changes associated with merger synergies. Our investigation is motivated<br />

by US court decisions, <strong>and</strong> enforcement policies in o<strong>the</strong>r jurisdictions,<br />

holding that synergies are relevant to <strong>the</strong> legality <strong>of</strong> a merger only to <strong>the</strong> extent<br />

that <strong>the</strong>y are passed on to consumers in <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> lower prices. In <strong>the</strong><br />

Staples–Office Depot merger case, for example, <strong>the</strong> court cited low estimated<br />

pass-through rates as an important reason that <strong>the</strong> claimed efficiencies did<br />

not outweigh <strong>the</strong> anticompetitive effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger.<br />

We apply <strong>the</strong> term “merger effects” to <strong>the</strong> prices increases from a merger<br />

<strong>and</strong> model <strong>the</strong>m as <strong>the</strong> difference between <strong>the</strong> non-cooperative equilibrium<br />

in which <strong>the</strong> merged products are priced independently, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> noncooperative<br />

equilibrium in which <strong>the</strong>y are priced jointly. In our terminology,<br />

“net” merger effects include impacts <strong>of</strong> synergies on prices, while “gross”<br />

merger effects do not. Differences between net <strong>and</strong> gross merger effects are<br />

<strong>the</strong> “pass-through effects” <strong>of</strong> merger synergies. They are modelled as <strong>the</strong><br />

difference between <strong>the</strong> post-merger equilibrium without synergies <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

post-merger equilibrium with <strong>the</strong>m.<br />

We derive expressions for <strong>the</strong> net <strong>and</strong> gross merger effects by applying<br />

<strong>the</strong> first step in Newton’s method at <strong>the</strong> pre-merger prices. This provides<br />

an estimator <strong>of</strong> merger effects using only information potentially available<br />

in <strong>the</strong> observed pre-merger equilibrium. Examination <strong>of</strong> this estimator indicates<br />

that gross merger effects <strong>and</strong> pass-through effects are closely related.<br />

Both are determined largely by <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it (dem<strong>and</strong>) concavity. In<br />

particular, holding first derivatives (e.g., dem<strong>and</strong> elasticities) constant, sec-<br />

1


ond derivatives (i.e., dem<strong>and</strong> concavity) determine both gross merger effects<br />

<strong>and</strong> pass-through.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> context <strong>of</strong> two major US merger cases, we demonstrate <strong>the</strong> practical<br />

importance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> association <strong>of</strong> high pass-through rates with large<br />

merger effects. The proposed WorldCom-Sprint merger illustrates that both<br />

pass-through <strong>and</strong> gross merger effects vary greatly with differing assumptions<br />

about <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>. The proposed Staples–Office Depot merger<br />

illustrates that price increase predictions <strong>and</strong> pass through predictions each<br />

<strong>of</strong>fer a check on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r. We find a likely inconsistency in <strong>the</strong> estimates<br />

made <strong>the</strong> experts testifying for <strong>the</strong> Federal Trade Commission.<br />

2 Merger <strong>Effects</strong> with Assumed Dem<strong>and</strong> Forms<br />

2.1 Merger <strong>Effects</strong> in Bertr<strong>and</strong> Industries<br />

Consumers dem<strong>and</strong> quantities given by <strong>the</strong> vector q = {q i } as a function<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> price vector p = {p i }, i = 1, . . . , n. Product i is supplied at cost c i<br />

which is a function <strong>of</strong> just q i . Pr<strong>of</strong>it from this product is<br />

π i = p i q i − c i . (1)<br />

These n products are <strong>the</strong> merging products <strong>and</strong> all competing products with<br />

prices that react to changes in <strong>the</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merging products.<br />

If each product is controlled by a different firm, maximizing <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

from just its product, <strong>the</strong> n first-order conditions for a Nash equilibrium are<br />

0 = ∂π i<br />

∂p i<br />

= q i + (p i − mc i ) ∂q i<br />

∂p i<br />

, (2)<br />

where<br />

mc i = dc i<br />

dq i<br />

(3)<br />

2


is <strong>the</strong> marginal cost <strong>of</strong> product i. We do not assume that marginal costs are<br />

constant, although this is <strong>of</strong>ten done in applied work. The effect <strong>of</strong> p j on q i ,<br />

with o<strong>the</strong>r prices held constant, is usually expressed in terms <strong>of</strong> elasticities:<br />

ɛ ij = p j<br />

q i<br />

∂q i<br />

∂p j<br />

. (4)<br />

The first-order conditions imply <strong>the</strong> familiar relation between price-cost margins<br />

<strong>and</strong> own-price dem<strong>and</strong> elasticities:<br />

p i − mc i<br />

p i<br />

= − 1<br />

ɛ ii<br />

. (5)<br />

When several products are controlled by <strong>the</strong> same firm, <strong>the</strong> dem<strong>and</strong><br />

interactions among its jointly owned products are internalized. If a single<br />

firm controls products 1 <strong>and</strong> 2, its first-order conditions are<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

0 = ∂(π 1 + π 2 )<br />

∂p 1<br />

= q 1 + (p 1 − mc 1 ) ∂q 1<br />

∂p 1<br />

+ (p 2 − mc 2 ) ∂q 2<br />

∂p 1<br />

(6)<br />

0 = ∂(π 1 + π 2 )<br />

∂p 2<br />

= q 2 + (p 1 − mc 1 ) ∂q 1<br />

∂p 2<br />

+ (p 2 − mc 2 ) ∂q 2<br />

∂p 2<br />

. (7)<br />

These conditions lead to different equilibrium pricing than equation 2. In<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> US Horizontal Merger Guidelines (1992), <strong>the</strong> difference between<br />

<strong>the</strong>se two equilibria is <strong>the</strong> “unilateral” effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger between sellers<br />

<strong>of</strong> products 1 <strong>and</strong> 2 in Bertr<strong>and</strong> oligopoly.<br />

2.2 Predicting Gross Merger <strong>Effects</strong><br />

To predict <strong>the</strong> gross merger effects from differentiated products mergers,<br />

economists commonly assume a particular functional form for dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

estimate dem<strong>and</strong> elasticities. Marginal costs are recovered from <strong>the</strong> firstorder<br />

conditions at <strong>the</strong> pre-merger equilibrium (e.g., equation 5), <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

gross merger effects are computed by solving <strong>the</strong> post-merger first-order conditions<br />

(e.g., equations 6 <strong>and</strong> 7), assuming <strong>the</strong> same or a different functional<br />

3


form for dem<strong>and</strong> as that used to estimate <strong>the</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> elasticities.<br />

The<br />

foregoing process, termed “merger simulation,” is described by Werden <strong>and</strong><br />

Froeb (1996) <strong>and</strong> Crooke et al. (1999). Nevo (2000), Hausman et al. (1994),<br />

Hausman <strong>and</strong> Leonard (1997), <strong>and</strong> Werden (2000) apply <strong>the</strong> technique to<br />

particular mergers.<br />

The simplest form <strong>of</strong> merger simulation employs a constant-elasticity approximation<br />

to an unknown dem<strong>and</strong> curve (e.g., Shapiro, 1996). Using an<br />

estimate <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> elasticity matrix at <strong>the</strong> pre-merger equilibrium, it is straightforward<br />

to compute post-merger prices. The constant-elasticity specification<br />

makes it unnecessary to have any information about non-merging products,<br />

as <strong>the</strong>ir prices do not change in response to <strong>the</strong> merger. However, if dem<strong>and</strong><br />

becomes more elastic as price increases, Crooke et al. (1999) show<br />

this approach can dramatically over-estimate merger effects.<br />

P<br />

22<br />

20<br />

200%<br />

18<br />

16<br />

14<br />

100%<br />

12<br />

10<br />

50%<br />

25%<br />

20 40 60 80 100<br />

Q<br />

Figure 1: Four Constant-<strong>Pass</strong>-<strong>Through</strong>-Rate Dem<strong>and</strong> Curves Plotted between<br />

<strong>the</strong> Competitive <strong>and</strong> Monopoly <strong>Price</strong>s<br />

4


Figure 1 illustrates why an erroneous assumption as to <strong>the</strong> functional<br />

form <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> can lead to a very large prediction error.<br />

It plots four<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> curves for a single-product industry, all defined by <strong>the</strong> functions<br />

⎧<br />

⎪⎨ (a − bp) θ/(1−θ) θ < 1<br />

q(p) = a exp(−bp) θ = 1<br />

⎪⎩<br />

(a + bp) θ/(1−θ) θ > 1.<br />

These dem<strong>and</strong> curves exhibit a constant pass-through rate, θ = ∂p/∂∆mc,<br />

where ∆mc is change in marginal cost resulting from merger synergies. By<br />

construction, <strong>the</strong> four dem<strong>and</strong> curves share <strong>the</strong> same price, quantity, <strong>and</strong><br />

elasticity (−2) at a single point, which we make <strong>the</strong> competitive equilibrium<br />

by assuming a constant marginal cost equal to that price. Figure 1 plots<br />

<strong>the</strong>se dem<strong>and</strong> curves between <strong>the</strong> common competitive equilibrium <strong>the</strong> four<br />

different monopoly equilibria. The differing concavities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> four dem<strong>and</strong><br />

curves result in substantially different monopoly prices. The top dem<strong>and</strong><br />

curve, associated with a 200% pass-through rate, yields a price–marginal cost<br />

margin at <strong>the</strong> monopoly price nearly ten times <strong>the</strong> margin with <strong>the</strong> bottom<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> curve, associated with a 25% pass-through rate. To foreshadow <strong>the</strong><br />

main result <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> paper, dem<strong>and</strong> concavity associated with higher monopoly<br />

prices is also associated with higher pass-through rates.<br />

2.3 Newton’s Method for Computing<br />

Post-Merger Equilibrium<br />

To compute equilibrium in industries with various ownership structures, we<br />

imagine that <strong>the</strong> pricing <strong>of</strong> each product is controlled by a single agent<br />

that may share in <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r products. This heuristic allows us to<br />

characterize different kinds <strong>of</strong> equilibria, including a pre-merger equilibrium<br />

in which all prices are set independently, <strong>and</strong> a post-merger equilibrium in<br />

which <strong>the</strong> merged firm maximizes <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its on its jointly owned<br />

5


products.<br />

To make this notion precise, we construct <strong>the</strong> “ownership-structure matrix,”<br />

W = {w ij }, with w ij indicating <strong>the</strong> share <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its from product j<br />

received by agent i setting <strong>the</strong> price <strong>of</strong> product i. Agent i thus maximizes<br />

Ω i = ∑ j<br />

w ij π j . (8)<br />

The pre-merger ownership structure, for example, may have W equal to <strong>the</strong><br />

identity matrix, while a post-merger ownership structure may have W equal<br />

to <strong>the</strong> identity matrix except for two <strong>of</strong>f-diagonal entries. Both structures<br />

are represented by <strong>the</strong> matrix<br />

⎛<br />

1 r<br />

⎞<br />

0<br />

W = ⎝ r 1 0 ⎠ . (9)<br />

0 0 1<br />

Setting r = 0 reflects <strong>the</strong> pre-merger structure, while setting r = 1 reflects<br />

<strong>the</strong> post-merger structure. The formulation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> model in terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> W<br />

matrix also can be used to incorporate partial ownership before or after a<br />

merger, as analyzed by O’Brien <strong>and</strong> Salop (2000).<br />

In this general formulation, <strong>the</strong> n first-order conditions are<br />

0 = ∂Ω i<br />

∂p i<br />

= ∑ j<br />

w ij<br />

∂π j<br />

∂p i<br />

= w ii q i + ∑ j<br />

w ij (p j − mc j ) ∂q j<br />

∂p i<br />

. (10)<br />

These first-order conditions apply both pre- <strong>and</strong> post-merger, using <strong>the</strong> relevant<br />

pre- <strong>and</strong> post-merger values for <strong>the</strong> w ij <strong>and</strong> mc j .<br />

To develop an expression for <strong>the</strong> net merger effect, we review how one<br />

uses Newton’s method to find a Nash equilibrium satisfying <strong>the</strong>se first-order<br />

conditions. Let z i = ∂Ω i /∂p i , <strong>and</strong> let z = {z i } be <strong>the</strong> vector <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se<br />

derivatives expressed as functions <strong>of</strong> p. To solve for simultaneous zeros <strong>of</strong> z,<br />

we take an initial estimate p (0) <strong>and</strong> successively refine <strong>the</strong> estimate by <strong>the</strong><br />

6


p (1) , p (2) , p (3) , . . . , generated by <strong>the</strong> rule<br />

p (k+1) = p (k) − A −1 z (k) , (11)<br />

where z (k)<br />

A = {a ij },<br />

= z(p (k) ) is <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> z at <strong>the</strong> latest approximation, <strong>and</strong><br />

a ij = ∂z i<br />

∂p j<br />

= w ii<br />

∂q i<br />

∂p j<br />

+ w ij<br />

∂q j<br />

∂p i<br />

+ ∑ k<br />

w ik (p k − mc k ) ∂2 q k<br />

∂p j ∂p i<br />

, (12)<br />

is also evaluated at p (k) . The A matrix, which indicates <strong>the</strong> slopes <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

derivatives <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it functions, also may be written<br />

A = ∂z<br />

∂p . (13)<br />

For notational simplicity, we suppress <strong>the</strong> fact that A is a function <strong>of</strong> prices<br />

<strong>and</strong> is affected by merger through both W <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> marginal costs.<br />

Newton’s method takes a first-order approximation to z at p (k) ,<br />

z ≈ z (k) + ∂z (<br />

p − p (k)) , (14)<br />

∂p<br />

<strong>and</strong> finds <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> p that sets this approximation equal to zero. To apply<br />

Newton’s method, it is necessary to specify an initial solution p (0) , <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> natural choice in merger analysis is <strong>the</strong> pre-merger equilibrium. Taking<br />

z (0) to be <strong>the</strong> first-order conditions evaluated with <strong>the</strong> post-merger ownership<br />

matrix at <strong>the</strong> pre-merger equilibrium prices, <strong>the</strong> first step in applying<br />

Newton’s method is<br />

p (1) = p (0) − A −1 z (0) . (15)<br />

Solving equation 15 requires evaluation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> second derivatives <strong>of</strong> q, as<br />

<strong>the</strong>y appear in A. These second derivatives determine <strong>the</strong> sharpness <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

peaks in <strong>the</strong> merged firm’s pr<strong>of</strong>it function or, put ano<strong>the</strong>r way, how much a<br />

small deviation from optimal pricing reduces pr<strong>of</strong>its.<br />

7


Equation 15 is a closed-form predictor <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> net merger effects using only<br />

information potentially available at <strong>the</strong> observed pre-merger equilibrium. If<br />

nothing is known about <strong>the</strong> functional form <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> function, equation<br />

15 <strong>of</strong>fers <strong>the</strong> best possible predictor <strong>of</strong> merger effects. If <strong>the</strong> post-merger<br />

first-order conditions are evaluated at <strong>the</strong> pre-merger marginal costs, i.e.,<br />

z (0) | mc pre, equation 15 yields <strong>the</strong> gross merger effect:<br />

∆p gme = −A −1 ( z (0) | mc pre<br />

)<br />

. (16)<br />

If <strong>the</strong> post-merger first-order conditions are evaluated at <strong>the</strong> marginal costs<br />

resulting from merger synergies, i.e., z (0) | mc post, equation 15 yields <strong>the</strong> net<br />

merger effect:<br />

( )<br />

∆p nme = −A −1 z (0) | mc post ≡ g(λ). (17)<br />

In both cases, A is evaluated at pre-merger prices <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> same marginal<br />

costs as <strong>the</strong> first-order conditions.<br />

The net merger effects predictor can be used to compute confidence intervals.<br />

For example, if equation 17 is parameterized by a vector <strong>of</strong> estimable<br />

parameters λ, <strong>and</strong> ˆλ is an estimator <strong>of</strong> λ with a limiting normal distribution<br />

√ n(ˆλ − λ) → D N(0, Σ) <strong>the</strong>n √ n(g(ˆλ) − g(λ)) → D N(0, (∇g)Σ(∇g) ′ ),<br />

provided that g is continuously differentiable at λ. Such analytic expressions<br />

are useful for identifying factors that make confidence intervals large<br />

<strong>and</strong> may suggest estimation strategies to reduce sampling variance. The<br />

λ vector may include ∆mc i as well as dem<strong>and</strong> parameters, reflecting <strong>the</strong><br />

uncertainty <strong>of</strong> synergy estimates.<br />

If pr<strong>of</strong>its are a quadratic function <strong>of</strong> prices, e.g., dem<strong>and</strong> is linear <strong>and</strong><br />

marginal costs are constant, Newton’s method converges to <strong>the</strong> post-merger<br />

equilibrium in one step, so our one-step approximation gives <strong>the</strong> exact solution.<br />

For o<strong>the</strong>r dem<strong>and</strong> functions, <strong>the</strong> approximation could be refined by<br />

8


applying Newton’s method iteratively, but that would require information<br />

about <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it functions at prices away from <strong>the</strong> observed equilibrium.<br />

In merger simulation, <strong>the</strong> source <strong>of</strong> such “information” always has been an<br />

arbitrary assumption about <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>. Without making such an<br />

assumption, equation 17 <strong>of</strong>fers <strong>the</strong> best possible approximation.<br />

An arbitrary assumption about <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> can be avoided if<br />

that form can be determined empirically, along with <strong>the</strong> elasticities at <strong>the</strong><br />

pre-merger equilibrium. The available data (commonly two years <strong>of</strong> scanner<br />

data), however, normally are insufficiently informative: The range <strong>of</strong> price<br />

variation is ra<strong>the</strong>r limited, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> relationship between prices <strong>and</strong> quantities<br />

is noisy. Without better data than normally is available, distinguishing<br />

among even large differences in pass-through rates is apt to be infeasible.<br />

Consider <strong>the</strong> problem <strong>of</strong> empirically distinguishing among <strong>the</strong> four dem<strong>and</strong><br />

curves in Figure 1. If prices were observed only between 10 <strong>and</strong> 12, <strong>the</strong>se<br />

four dem<strong>and</strong> curves would be empirically indistinguishable unless <strong>the</strong> data<br />

fit extraordinarily well.<br />

3 <strong>Pass</strong>-<strong>Through</strong> <strong>Rates</strong> <strong>and</strong> Gross Merger <strong>Effects</strong><br />

3.1 <strong>Pass</strong>-<strong>Through</strong> <strong>Rates</strong><br />

We now consider how equilibrium pricing is affected by changes in costs, as<br />

examined in <strong>the</strong> context <strong>of</strong> monopoly by Bulow <strong>and</strong> Pleiderer (1983) <strong>and</strong><br />

in <strong>the</strong> context <strong>of</strong> differentiated products oligopoly by Anderson, De Palma,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Kreider (2001). We assume <strong>the</strong> effect <strong>of</strong> merger synergies on marginal<br />

cost is invariant to output, but we do not assume that marginal cost itself is<br />

invariant to output. In particular, merger synergies are assumed to shift <strong>the</strong><br />

marginal cost functions for <strong>the</strong> merged firm’s products by ∆mc = {∆mc i },<br />

with ∆mc i independent <strong>of</strong> q i , so each post-merger cost function equals that<br />

9


pre-merger plus q i ∆mc i .<br />

We assume <strong>the</strong> equilibrium prices are continuous <strong>and</strong> differentiable functions<br />

<strong>of</strong> ∆mc. Let<br />

{ }<br />

∂p<br />

∂∆mc = ∂pi<br />

∂∆mc j<br />

(18)<br />

be <strong>the</strong> matrix <strong>of</strong> rates at which marginal cost changes affect equilibrium<br />

prices, with <strong>the</strong> diagonal entries being <strong>the</strong> rates at which firms pass-through<br />

changes in <strong>the</strong>ir own marginal costs. Using <strong>the</strong> implicit function <strong>the</strong>orem<br />

<strong>and</strong> differentiating <strong>the</strong> first-order conditions for post-merger equilibrium<br />

(equation 10), it is straightforward to compute <strong>the</strong> rate at which changes in<br />

marginal cost are passed through to prices. The pass-through-rate matrix<br />

is<br />

where B = {b ij } <strong>and</strong><br />

( )<br />

∂p ∂z −1 ( ) ∂z<br />

∂∆mc = − = −A −1 B, (19)<br />

∂p ∂∆mc<br />

b ij =<br />

∂z i<br />

∂∆mc j<br />

= −w ij<br />

∂q j<br />

∂p i<br />

. (20)<br />

Hence, <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> marginal cost changes on equilibrium price changes<br />

is approximated to <strong>the</strong> first order by<br />

∆p spt ≈ −A −1 B∆mc, (21)<br />

where <strong>the</strong> subscript “spt” denotes “synergy pass through.” The pass-throughrate<br />

matrix (equation 19) indicates <strong>the</strong> extent to which marginal cost savings<br />

from a merger are passed through to consumer prices in <strong>the</strong> post-merger<br />

equilibrium <strong>and</strong> can be thought <strong>of</strong> as a predictor <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> gross benefits <strong>of</strong> a<br />

merger (under a consumer-welfare st<strong>and</strong>ard, which ignores pr<strong>of</strong>it increases).<br />

Equation 19 is a function <strong>of</strong> both prices <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> ownership structure,<br />

W, so pass-through rates in <strong>the</strong> pre-merger equilibrium differ from those in<br />

<strong>the</strong> post-merger equilibrium. The difference between pre- <strong>and</strong> post-merger<br />

10


pass-through rates is most important for <strong>the</strong> cross pass-through rates <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

products <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merging firms. This difference depends on <strong>the</strong> properties<br />

<strong>of</strong> particular dem<strong>and</strong> systems, <strong>and</strong> almost anything is possible. Cross passthrough<br />

rates may be positive pre merger but negative post merger, <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong>y may be substantially greater pre merger even if positive both pre <strong>and</strong><br />

post merger.<br />

The W matrix incorporated in equation 21 through A <strong>and</strong> B reflects<br />

<strong>the</strong> post-merger ownership structure, while <strong>the</strong> derivatives in equation 21 are<br />

evaluated at pre-merger prices. Like <strong>the</strong> gross <strong>and</strong> net merger effect predictors,<br />

<strong>the</strong> synergy effect predictor incorporates only information potentially<br />

available at <strong>the</strong> observed pre-merger equilibrium.<br />

The second-order conditions for Bertr<strong>and</strong> equilibrium require that <strong>the</strong><br />

A matrix be negative definite, <strong>and</strong> this imposes restrictions on <strong>the</strong> passthrough<br />

matrix, −A −1 B.<br />

For example, in an industry characterized by<br />

single-product firms, −A −1 is positive definite <strong>and</strong> B is a diagonal matrix,<br />

with b ii = −∂q i /∂p i along <strong>the</strong> main diagonal. This implies that own passthrough<br />

rates are positive. And in a symmetric industry with single-product<br />

firms, all <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> b ii are <strong>the</strong> same, so B is a scalar times <strong>the</strong> identity matrix,<br />

which implies that <strong>the</strong> pass-through matrix is positive definite.<br />

3.2 The Relationship Between <strong>Pass</strong>-<strong>Through</strong><br />

<strong>Rates</strong> <strong>and</strong> Merger <strong>Effects</strong><br />

Adding <strong>the</strong> gross merger effect <strong>of</strong> equation 16 <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> synergy effect <strong>of</strong><br />

equation 21 yields <strong>the</strong> net merger effect:<br />

( )<br />

∆p gme + ∆p spt ≈ −A −1 z (0) | mc pre + B∆mc . (22)<br />

Because A is <strong>the</strong> matrix <strong>of</strong> derivatives with respect to prices <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> vector <strong>of</strong><br />

first-order conditions for pr<strong>of</strong>it maximization, equation 22 clearly indicates<br />

11


<strong>the</strong> influence <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> second derivatives, through A, on both <strong>the</strong> gross<br />

merger effect <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> pass-through effect. The terms in <strong>the</strong> paren<strong>the</strong>ses in<br />

equation 22 include only first derivatives: z (0) | mc pre is <strong>the</strong> vector <strong>of</strong> firstorder<br />

conditions evaluated at <strong>the</strong> pre-merger marginal costs (equation 12),<br />

while B is <strong>the</strong> matrix <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> partial derivatives multiplied by pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

ownership shares (equation 20). Holding <strong>the</strong>se two terms constant, <strong>the</strong>re<br />

is a one-to-one relationship between gross merger effects <strong>and</strong> pass-through<br />

rates. This relationship is manifest in Figure 1 (<strong>and</strong> in Table 2 below).<br />

It is easy to underst<strong>and</strong> why <strong>the</strong> gross merger effects <strong>and</strong> pass-through<br />

rates both depend on dem<strong>and</strong> concavity. The first-order conditions characterizing<br />

equilibrium are <strong>the</strong> first derivatives <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it functions. The<br />

extent to which equilibrium is displaced by a merger or marginal cost reduction<br />

thus depends on <strong>the</strong> derivatives <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> first-order conditions, <strong>and</strong><br />

hence on concavity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it function, which in this model is determined<br />

by dem<strong>and</strong> concavity.<br />

Data relating to <strong>the</strong> ab<strong>and</strong>oned WorldCom-Sprint merger can be used<br />

to illustrate <strong>the</strong> relationship between merger effects <strong>and</strong> pass-through rates.<br />

Shares <strong>and</strong> estimated elasticities <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> for residential long-distance service<br />

are taken from Hausman’s (2000) submission to <strong>the</strong> Federal Communications<br />

Commission in opposition to <strong>the</strong> merger. We assume a common<br />

pre-merger price <strong>of</strong> $0.07 per minute. AT&T was <strong>the</strong> largest carrier with<br />

63.4% <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> domestic residential long-distance minutes, followed by World-<br />

Com with 16.4% <strong>and</strong> Sprint with 5.0%. We place all o<strong>the</strong>r firms in <strong>the</strong><br />

residual category, “Emerging,” treating <strong>the</strong>m as a single price-setting entity<br />

in <strong>the</strong> simulations below. This treatment imparts a slight upward bias<br />

to <strong>the</strong> simulated merger effects. Hausman’s estimated elasticity matrix is<br />

presented in Table 1. The columns relate to prices <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> rows relate to<br />

12


quantities, so <strong>the</strong> figure in <strong>the</strong> third column <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> first row is <strong>the</strong> elasticity<br />

<strong>of</strong> AT&T’s dem<strong>and</strong> with respect to Sprint’s price.<br />

Table 1: Estimated Elasticity Matrix for Residential Long Distance Carriers<br />

AT&T WorldCom Sprint Emerging<br />

AT&T −1.12 0.09 0.03 0.16<br />

WorldCom 0.50 −1.33 0.06 0.23<br />

Sprint 0.61 0.22 −1.81 0.30<br />

Emerging 0.47 0.12 0.04 −1.33<br />

Three different commonly used dem<strong>and</strong> systems—linear, AIDS (without<br />

income effects), <strong>and</strong> constant elasticity—are calibrated to <strong>the</strong> same premerger<br />

equilibrium, i.e., <strong>the</strong> same prices, quantities, <strong>and</strong> elasticities (see<br />

Crooke et al. (1999) for calibration details). Table 2 displays <strong>the</strong> resulting<br />

merger effects as well as <strong>the</strong> marginal pass-trough rates at <strong>the</strong> post-merger<br />

equilibrium. We suppose that all <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger synergies accrue to <strong>the</strong><br />

Sprint product <strong>and</strong> examine <strong>the</strong> pass-through rates to <strong>the</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> all four<br />

products. These pass-through rates are not approximations; <strong>the</strong> assumption<br />

<strong>of</strong> specific dem<strong>and</strong> forms makes approximation unnecessary.<br />

Table 2: Gross Merger <strong>Effects</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Pass</strong>-<strong>Through</strong> <strong>Rates</strong> for <strong>the</strong> WorldCom-<br />

Sprint Merger<br />

Dem<strong>and</strong> Merger Effect <strong>Pass</strong>-through Rate from Sprint Cost to<br />

Form %∆p W C+Sp AT&T WorldCom Sprint Emerging<br />

Linear 2.3 0.007 0.001 0.502 0.008<br />

AIDS 13.8 0.046 0.032 1.807 0.052<br />

Isoelastic 16.4 0.000 −0.343 3.838 0.000<br />

The striking feature <strong>of</strong> Table 2 is <strong>the</strong> difference across dem<strong>and</strong> systems<br />

in predicted gross merger effects <strong>and</strong> pass-through rates.<br />

With isoelastic<br />

13


dem<strong>and</strong>, both <strong>the</strong> merger effect <strong>and</strong> Sprint’s own pass-through rate (from<br />

Sprint’s marginal costs to Sprint’s price) are over seven times as large as<br />

<strong>the</strong>y are with linear dem<strong>and</strong>. Since all dem<strong>and</strong> systems have <strong>the</strong> same<br />

elasticities by construction, <strong>the</strong> differences across systems are due to <strong>the</strong><br />

different second derivatives.<br />

4 Compensating Marginal Cost Reductions<br />

While dem<strong>and</strong> second derivatives are important determinants <strong>of</strong> both merger<br />

<strong>and</strong> pass-through effects, Werden (1996) <strong>and</strong> Stenneck <strong>and</strong> Verboven (2001)<br />

have shown that <strong>the</strong> marginal cost reductions necessary to keep prices constant<br />

depend only on first derivatives, prices, <strong>and</strong> quantities. These “compensating<br />

marginal cost reductions” can be computed by setting <strong>the</strong> term<br />

in paren<strong>the</strong>ses in equation 22 to zero, <strong>and</strong> solving for ∆mc:<br />

∆mc comp = −B −1 z (0) | mc pre . (23)<br />

Compensating marginal cost reductions are robust with respect to different<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> forms, in that <strong>the</strong>y do not depend on <strong>the</strong> concavity <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>.<br />

This is easily seen from <strong>the</strong> fact <strong>the</strong> matrix B <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> vector z (0) contain<br />

only first-order terms. And since prices do not change, <strong>the</strong> non-merging<br />

firms’ first-order conditions remain at zero, so <strong>the</strong> elements <strong>of</strong> z (0) corresponding<br />

to <strong>the</strong> non-merging firms are zero. The matrix W, <strong>and</strong> thus <strong>the</strong><br />

matrix B, has a block-diagonal form, with <strong>the</strong> merging products forming<br />

a block. Because <strong>the</strong> inverse <strong>of</strong> B is also block diagonal, <strong>the</strong> compensating<br />

marginal cost reductions depend only on <strong>the</strong> elements corresponding<br />

to <strong>the</strong> merging products. Using Hausman’s estimated elasticities from <strong>the</strong><br />

WorldCom-Sprint merger, <strong>the</strong> compensating marginal cost reductions are<br />

19% for Sprint <strong>and</strong> 13% for WorldCom, measured as a percentage <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

14


pre-merger marginal costs.<br />

When merger synergies exactly <strong>of</strong>fset <strong>the</strong> gross merger effects, <strong>the</strong> passthrough<br />

rates can be computed by dividing <strong>the</strong> gross merger effect, ∆p gme ,<br />

by <strong>the</strong> compensating marginal cost reductions, ∆mc comp . Thus, <strong>the</strong>re is a<br />

simple relationship between compensating marginal cost reductions, gross<br />

merger effects, <strong>and</strong> merging product dem<strong>and</strong> elasticities. This relationship<br />

allows a useful analysis <strong>of</strong> pass-through rates that does not depend on second<br />

derivatives <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> hence is not dependent on its functional form.<br />

5 <strong>Pass</strong> <strong>Through</strong> in Staples–Office Depot<br />

As discussed by Dalkir <strong>and</strong> Warren-Boulton (2004), in 1997 <strong>the</strong> Federal<br />

Trade Commission successfully challenged <strong>the</strong> merger <strong>of</strong> Staples <strong>and</strong> Office<br />

Depot, <strong>the</strong> two largest <strong>of</strong>fice supply superstore chains in <strong>the</strong> US. In opposing<br />

<strong>the</strong> merger, <strong>the</strong> FTC’s economic experts estimated that 85% <strong>of</strong> industrywide<br />

marginal cost reductions had been passed through to retail prices,<br />

while only 15% <strong>of</strong> firm-specific marginal cost reductions had been passed<br />

through (Ashenfelter et al., 1998). The court relied on <strong>the</strong> latter estimate<br />

in determining that synergies generated by <strong>the</strong> merger were insufficient to<br />

prevent price increases.<br />

As discussed by Ashenfelter et al. (2004) <strong>and</strong> Baker (1999), <strong>the</strong> FTC’s<br />

economic experts also used panel data to estimate <strong>the</strong> price effect <strong>of</strong> changing<br />

<strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>fice superstores, assuming no synergies. Public sources<br />

report only nationwide average price increase predictions for <strong>the</strong> merger,<br />

reflecting both cities in which <strong>the</strong> merging firms were <strong>the</strong> only <strong>of</strong>fice supply<br />

superstores <strong>and</strong> cities in which <strong>the</strong>re was a third superstore. Based <strong>the</strong><br />

reported estimates, we assume a predicted price increase <strong>of</strong> 7.5% for <strong>the</strong><br />

cities with just <strong>the</strong> merging firms.<br />

15


The analysis <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> preceding section provides a check for <strong>the</strong> consistency<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> estimated firm-specific pass-through rate with <strong>the</strong> predicted price increase.<br />

Assuming <strong>the</strong> merging firms were symmetric in all relevant respects,<br />

Werden (1996) shows that <strong>the</strong> compensating marginal cost reduction relative<br />

to pre-merger price, can be computed as<br />

∆mc<br />

p<br />

= − dm<br />

1 − d , (24)<br />

where m is <strong>the</strong> price-marginal cost margin <strong>and</strong> d is <strong>the</strong> diversion ratio from<br />

one superstore to ano<strong>the</strong>r, d = ɛ ij /ɛ ii . Rearranging <strong>the</strong> result at <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> preceding section, <strong>the</strong> implied compensating marginal cost reductions<br />

are given by <strong>the</strong> gross merger effect (7.5%) divided by <strong>the</strong> firm-specific passthrough<br />

rate (15%). This yields a compensating marginal cost reduction <strong>of</strong><br />

50% <strong>of</strong> price for both merging firms, so equation 24 implies d = 1/(1 + 2m).<br />

Symmetry also implies <strong>the</strong> aggregate elasticity <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> for <strong>of</strong>fice superstores,<br />

ɛ, divided by <strong>the</strong> individual firm own-price elasticity, ɛ ii , equals<br />

1 − d. Since Betr<strong>and</strong> equilibrium implies ɛ ii = −1/m, <strong>the</strong> solution for d as<br />

a function <strong>of</strong> m implies ɛ = −2/(1 + 2m). To check for consistency, this<br />

relationship implied by <strong>the</strong> price-increase <strong>and</strong> pass-through rate predictions<br />

can be compared with what may have been known about margins <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

aggregate elasticity <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>fice superstore dem<strong>and</strong>.<br />

We suspect that aggregate<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> for <strong>of</strong>fice supply superstores was known to be ra<strong>the</strong>r elastic<br />

because <strong>the</strong>re were many alternative sources for <strong>of</strong>fice supplies. If so, <strong>the</strong><br />

price-increase prediction was inconsistent with <strong>the</strong> pass-through prediction,<br />

since ɛ < −2 implies m < 0, which surely was not <strong>the</strong> case. This conclusion,<br />

however, depends on <strong>the</strong> assumption <strong>of</strong> Bertr<strong>and</strong> competition, <strong>and</strong> we do<br />

not know whe<strong>the</strong>r this is what <strong>the</strong> FTC had in mind.<br />

An additional check on <strong>the</strong> internal consistency <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> predictions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

FTC’s economists follows from Section 3.1. This check employs <strong>the</strong> 15%<br />

16


firm-specific pass-through rate estimated <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> estimated industry-wide<br />

pass-through rate <strong>of</strong> 85%. In a symmetric Bertr<strong>and</strong> industry, <strong>the</strong> industrywide<br />

pass-through rate is <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> elements <strong>of</strong> any row in <strong>the</strong> passthrough<br />

matrix. Assuming symmetry <strong>and</strong> that both <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> estimates from<br />

Ashenfelter et al. (1998) were correct, it is simple to compute <strong>the</strong> implied <strong>of</strong>fdiagonal,<br />

or cross, pass-through rates—those from <strong>the</strong> costs <strong>of</strong> one merging<br />

firm to <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r merging firm’s price.<br />

In two-superstore cities, <strong>the</strong> cross pass-through rates in each row would<br />

have to be 70%, causing <strong>the</strong> pass-through matrix not to be positive definite,<br />

<strong>and</strong> causing <strong>the</strong> second-order conditions for Bertr<strong>and</strong> equilibrium not to be<br />

satisfied. Ano<strong>the</strong>r way to see this is to translate <strong>the</strong> cross pass-through rates<br />

into slopes <strong>of</strong> best-response functions. This translation is straightforward<br />

because <strong>the</strong> cross pass-through effect is just a response to a rival’s price<br />

change. The slopes <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two best-response functions are just <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> cross <strong>and</strong> own pass-through rates, which is 70/15. With <strong>the</strong>se slopes, <strong>the</strong><br />

best-response functions would not cross, <strong>and</strong> equilibrium would not exist.<br />

Finally, even if <strong>the</strong> estimated pass-through rates were correct <strong>and</strong> accurate<br />

in <strong>the</strong> Staples–Office Depot case, <strong>the</strong>y may have been misleading,<br />

because <strong>the</strong> merger would have caused <strong>the</strong> pass-through rates to change.<br />

The changes in prices resulting from <strong>the</strong> merger, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> changes in ownership<br />

that <strong>the</strong> merger bring about, both affect <strong>the</strong> pass-through rates. Postmerger<br />

pass-through rates could not have been estimated directly, but could<br />

have been constructed from <strong>the</strong> parameters <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm-level pr<strong>of</strong>it functions.<br />

6 Discussion<br />

The net price effects <strong>of</strong> mergers is <strong>the</strong> touchstone for <strong>the</strong> legality <strong>of</strong> mergers<br />

under current law in <strong>the</strong> US <strong>and</strong> many o<strong>the</strong>r jurisdictions, <strong>and</strong> we present a<br />

17


igorous methodology for implementing that policy. We show that <strong>the</strong>re is a<br />

strong relationship between <strong>the</strong> gross consumer costs imposed by a merger,<br />

i.e., <strong>the</strong> increases in consumer prices absent synergies, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> gross consumer<br />

benefits derived from <strong>the</strong> merger, i.e., <strong>the</strong> pass through to consumer<br />

prices <strong>of</strong> marginal cost reductions from merger synergies. Holding constant<br />

<strong>the</strong> first-order conditions at <strong>the</strong> pre-merger equilibrium, higher-order properties<br />

that cause larger price increases absent synergies also cause merger<br />

synergies to be passed through at higher rates.<br />

The gross price effects <strong>and</strong> pass-through effects <strong>of</strong> mergers can be jointly<br />

estimated using <strong>the</strong> net merger predictor presented in equation 17. The<br />

second derivatives <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it (dem<strong>and</strong>) function play a vital role in determining<br />

both effects, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> estimator <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> net merger effect is crucially<br />

dependent on <strong>the</strong>m. As an alternative to estimating dem<strong>and</strong> second derivatives,<br />

one can compute <strong>the</strong> compensating marginal cost reductions necessary<br />

to <strong>of</strong>fset <strong>the</strong> merger price effects. These depend only on <strong>the</strong> first-order conditions<br />

at <strong>the</strong> pre-merger equilibrium, which in principle are observable. By<br />

comparing likely cost reductions with <strong>the</strong>se compensating marginal cost reductions,<br />

it generally is possible to determine whe<strong>the</strong>r prices are likely to<br />

rise or fall.<br />

The foregoing is predicated on <strong>the</strong> assumption <strong>of</strong> Bertr<strong>and</strong> competition,<br />

but similar results obtain with o<strong>the</strong>r Nash non-cooperative equilibria. The<br />

conditions characterizing such equilibria are first derivatives <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

functions, so <strong>the</strong> displacement <strong>of</strong> equilibrium by ei<strong>the</strong>r merger or marginal<br />

cost reductions is determined by <strong>the</strong> concavity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it functions. In<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r models, however, pr<strong>of</strong>it concavity may not be controlled by <strong>the</strong> form<br />

<strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>. Tschantz, Crooke, <strong>and</strong> Froeb (2000) show that <strong>the</strong> distribution<br />

<strong>of</strong> costs is critical in a first- or second-price private-values auction model.<br />

18


Generalizations <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Bertr<strong>and</strong> model may affect pass through significantly.<br />

Froeb, Tschantz, <strong>and</strong> Werden (2002) show that adding a monopoly<br />

retail sector downstream <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merging Bertr<strong>and</strong> competitors may change<br />

nothing or everything, depending on <strong>the</strong> rules <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> game <strong>and</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

contracts between <strong>the</strong> retailer <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> upstream competitors. One possible<br />

outcome is no pass through at all. We have not explored <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> nonlinear<br />

pricing or long-term contracts between <strong>the</strong> merging firms <strong>and</strong> ultimate<br />

consumers, but ei<strong>the</strong>r could make it possible for fixed-cost reductions to be<br />

pass through, although <strong>the</strong>y are not in Betr<strong>and</strong> competition. Merger policy<br />

in both <strong>the</strong> US <strong>and</strong> Europe gives little or no weight to fixed cost-reductions<br />

from merger synergies because <strong>the</strong>y are not expected to be passed through.<br />

19


Acknowledgments<br />

Support for this project was provided by <strong>the</strong> Dean’s fund for faculty research.<br />

We acknowledge useful comments from Jon Baker, Tim Brennan,<br />

Serdar Dalkir, Joe Farrell, Gautam Gowrisankaran, P.J.J. Herings, Gregory<br />

Leonard, John Ratcliffe, Frank Verboven, <strong>and</strong> Wes Wilson.<br />

References<br />

Anderson, S., A. de Palma, B. Kreider, 2001. Tax Incidence in Differentiated<br />

Product Oligopoly, Journal <strong>of</strong> Public Economics 81, 173–92.<br />

Ashenfelter, O., D. Ashmore, J.B. Baker, S.-M. McKernan, 1998. Identifying<br />

<strong>the</strong> Firm-Specific Cost <strong>Pass</strong>-<strong>Through</strong> Rate, FTC Working Paper No.<br />

217.<br />

Ashenfelter, O., D. Ashmore, J.B. Baker, S. Gleason <strong>and</strong> D.S. Hosken,<br />

2004. Econometric Methods in Staples, in: John Harkrider, ed., Econometrics<br />

in Antitrust (American Bar Association Antitrust Section).<br />

Baker, J.B., 1999. Econometric Analysis in FTC v. Staples, Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Public Policy & Marketing 18, 11–21.<br />

Bulow, J. <strong>and</strong> P. Pfleiderer, 1983. A Note on <strong>the</strong> Effect <strong>of</strong> Cost Changes<br />

on <strong>Price</strong>s, Journal <strong>of</strong> Political Economy 91, 182-85.<br />

Crooke, P., L. Froeb, S. Tschantz, G.J. Werden, 1999. The <strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> Assumed<br />

Dem<strong>and</strong> Form on Simulated Post-Merger Equilibria, Review <strong>of</strong> Industrial<br />

Organization 15, 205–17.<br />

20


Dalkir, S. <strong>and</strong> F.R. Warren-Boulton, 2004. <strong>Price</strong>s, Market Definition, <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> Merger: Staples–Office Depot, in: J.E. Kwoka, Jr. <strong>and</strong> L.J.<br />

White, eds., The Antitrust Revolution (Oxford, New York) 52–72.<br />

Froeb, L., S. Tschantz, G.J. Werden, 2002. Vertical Restraints <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> Upstream Horizontal <strong>Mergers</strong>, Owen Working Paper, V<strong>and</strong>erbilt<br />

University.<br />

Hausman, J., 2000. Declaration <strong>of</strong> Jerry Hausman, submitted to <strong>the</strong> Federal<br />

Communications Commission.<br />

Hausman, J., G. Leonard, J.D. Zona, 1994. Competitive Analysis with<br />

Differentiated Products, Annales d’Economie et Statistique 34, 159–80.<br />

Hausman, J. <strong>and</strong> G. Leonard, 1997. Competitive Analysis with Differentiated<br />

Products, George Mason Law Review 34, 159–80.<br />

Nevo, A., 2000. <strong>Mergers</strong> with Differentiated Products: The Case <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Ready-to-Eat Cereal Industry, RAND Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics 31, 395–421.<br />

O’Brien, D. <strong>and</strong> S. Salop, 2000. Competitive <strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> Partial Ownership:<br />

Financial Interest <strong>and</strong> Corporate Control, Antitrust Law Journal 67, 559–<br />

614.<br />

Shapiro, C., 1996. <strong>Mergers</strong> with Differentiated Products, Antitrust (Spring)<br />

23–30.<br />

Stennek, J. <strong>and</strong> F. Verboven, 2001. Merger Control <strong>and</strong> Enterprise Competitiveness:<br />

Empirical Analysis <strong>and</strong> Policy Recommendations, available<br />

at http://www.iui.se/wp/Wp556/IUIWp556.pdf.<br />

Tschantz, S., P. Crooke, L. Froeb, 2000. <strong>Mergers</strong> in Sealed versus Oral<br />

Auctions, International Journal <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Economics <strong>of</strong> Business, 7, 201–212.<br />

21


U.S. Department <strong>of</strong> Justice <strong>and</strong> Federal Trade Commission, 1992. Horizontal<br />

Merger Guidelines, 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) 13,104.<br />

Werden, G.J., 1996. A Robust Test for Consumer Welfare Enhancing <strong>Mergers</strong><br />

Among Sellers <strong>of</strong> Differentiated Products, Journal <strong>of</strong> Industrial Economics<br />

44, 409–13.<br />

Werden, G.J., 2000. Expert Report in United States v. Interstate Bakeries<br />

<strong>and</strong> Continental Baking Co., International Journal <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Economics <strong>of</strong><br />

Business 7, 139–48.<br />

Werden, G.J. <strong>and</strong> L.M. Froeb, 1996. Simulation as an Alternative to Structural<br />

Merger Policy in Differentiated Products Industries, in: M. Coate <strong>and</strong><br />

A. Kleit, eds., The Economics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Antitrust Process (Kluwer, New York)<br />

65–88.<br />

22

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!