30.12.2014 Views

The Limit Order Book and the Break-Even ... - Marriott School

The Limit Order Book and the Break-Even ... - Marriott School

The Limit Order Book and the Break-Even ... - Marriott School

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

THE LIMIT ORDER BOOK AND THE BREAK-EVEN CONDITIONS REVISITED 7<br />

<strong>the</strong> order size, v(δ) = E[ṽ|˜δ = δ], <strong>and</strong> v + (δ) = E[ṽ|˜δ > δ]. <strong>The</strong> expected profit of a<br />

marginal offer is<br />

u(x, y) = E(x − ṽ)I { δ>y} e = x(1 − F (y)) −<br />

= (x − v + (y))(1 − F (y))<br />

∫ ∞<br />

y<br />

v(u)dF (u)<br />

<strong>The</strong> relevant region is D = {(x, y) : F (y) < 1}, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> probability of execution is<br />

ɛ(x, y) = (1 − F (y)).<br />

2. <strong>The</strong> <strong>Break</strong> <strong>Even</strong> Conditions<br />

Following Rock (1990) <strong>and</strong> Glosten (1994), it is common to posit that when <strong>the</strong>re<br />

are infinitely many liquidity suppliers <strong>and</strong> it is costless to post offers <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> supply<br />

function satisfies <strong>the</strong> break even conditions:<br />

[<br />

]<br />

x ≤ E ṽ|˜δ(y(·)) > y(x)<br />

with equality whenever dy(x) > 0. <strong>The</strong> right h<strong>and</strong> side is commonly called <strong>the</strong> “upper<br />

tail expectation.” We may have a strict inequality because <strong>the</strong>re are prices at which<br />

even competitive liquidity suppliers do not offer shares (e.g., prices that are below<br />

<strong>the</strong> ask price).<br />

An economic environment is said to be regular if: (i) <strong>The</strong>re is a unique supply function,<br />

which we denote by y ∞ (·), that satisfies <strong>the</strong> break even condition, <strong>and</strong> (ii) In <strong>the</strong><br />

relevant region D, <strong>the</strong> sign of u(·, ·) is negative above <strong>the</strong> graph of y ∞ (x) <strong>and</strong> positive<br />

below <strong>the</strong> graph. 8 We denote by ask ∞ <strong>the</strong> ask price that corresponds to <strong>the</strong> supply<br />

function y ∞ (·).<br />

Though our analysis is general, we are only interested in regular economic environments<br />

where <strong>the</strong> argument for <strong>the</strong> break even conditions sounds appealing. In a<br />

regular economic environment, <strong>the</strong> following procedure can be used to construct <strong>the</strong><br />

supply function y ∞ (·): ask ∞ is <strong>the</strong> smallest positive root of x → u(x, 0). For all<br />

x < ask ∞ , we set y ∞ (x) = 0. For all x > ask ∞ , we set y ∞ (x) to be <strong>the</strong> value where<br />

<strong>the</strong> function y → u(x, y) changes signs.<br />

8 <strong>The</strong> graph of y ∞ (·) is a subset of <strong>the</strong> positive quadrant: it is <strong>the</strong> collection of all <strong>the</strong> pairs (x, y ∞ (x)).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!