15.05.2015 Views

- 1 - BEFORE THE PUBLIC UTILITIES COMMISSION OF ... - BOMA SF

- 1 - BEFORE THE PUBLIC UTILITIES COMMISSION OF ... - BOMA SF

- 1 - BEFORE THE PUBLIC UTILITIES COMMISSION OF ... - BOMA SF

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>BEFORE</strong> <strong>THE</strong> <strong>PUBLIC</strong> <strong>UTILITIES</strong> <strong>COMMISSION</strong><br />

<strong>OF</strong> <strong>THE</strong> STATE <strong>OF</strong> CALIFORNIA<br />

Application of Pacific Gas and Electric Company<br />

for Authority to Implement Default CPP Rate<br />

Options For Large Customers<br />

Application No. 05-01-016<br />

(Filed January 20, 2005)<br />

Southern California Edison Company’s (U 388-E)<br />

Application for Approval of Rate Design Proposal<br />

For Large Customers<br />

Application No. 05-01-017<br />

(Filed January 20, 2005)<br />

Investigation on the Commission’s Own Motion<br />

into the Rate, Operations, Practices, Service, and<br />

Facilities of Southern California Edison Company<br />

Application No. 05-01-018<br />

(Filed January 20, 2005)<br />

OPENING BRIEF<br />

<strong>OF</strong><br />

<strong>THE</strong> BUILDING OWNERS AND MANAGERS ASSOCIATION<br />

<strong>OF</strong> SAN FRANCISCO,<br />

AND<br />

<strong>THE</strong> BUILDING OWNERS AND MANAGERS ASSOCIATION<br />

<strong>OF</strong> CALIFORNIA<br />

March 14, 2005<br />

Bill F. Roberts, Ph.D.<br />

ECONOMIC SCIENCES CORPORATION<br />

1516 LeRoy Avenue<br />

Berkeley, CA 94708<br />

(510) 841-6869<br />

bill@econsci.com<br />

For:<br />

<strong>THE</strong> BUILDING OWNERS AND MANAGERS<br />

ASSOCIATION <strong>OF</strong> SAN FRANCISCO AND,<br />

<strong>THE</strong> BUILDING OWNERS AND MANAGERS<br />

ASSOCIATION <strong>OF</strong> CALIFORNIA<br />

- 1 -


<strong>BEFORE</strong> <strong>THE</strong> <strong>PUBLIC</strong> <strong>UTILITIES</strong> <strong>COMMISSION</strong><br />

<strong>OF</strong> <strong>THE</strong> STATE <strong>OF</strong> CALIFORNIA<br />

Application of Pacific Gas and Electric Company<br />

for Authority to Implement Default CPP Rate<br />

Options For Large Customers<br />

Application No. 05-01-016<br />

(Filed January 20, 2005)<br />

Southern California Edison Company’s (U 388-E)<br />

Application for Approval of Rate Design Proposal<br />

For Large Customers<br />

Application No. 05-01-017<br />

(Filed January 20, 2005)<br />

Investigation on the Commission’s Own Motion<br />

into the Rate, Operations, Practices, Service, and<br />

Facilities of Southern California Edison Company<br />

Application No. 05-01-018<br />

(Filed January 20, 2005)<br />

OPENING BRIEF<br />

<strong>OF</strong><br />

<strong>THE</strong> BUILDING OWNERS AND MANAGERS ASSOCIATION<br />

<strong>OF</strong> SAN FRANCISCO,<br />

AND<br />

<strong>THE</strong> BUILDING OWNERS AND MANAGERS ASSOCIATION<br />

<strong>OF</strong> CALIFORNIA<br />

In accordance with the procedural schedule established by the<br />

Presiding Administrative Law Judge 1 , the Building Owners and Managers<br />

Association of San Francisco (<strong>BOMA</strong> <strong>SF</strong>) and the Building Owners and<br />

Managers Association of California (<strong>BOMA</strong> Cal) hereby respectfully submit their<br />

conclusions, recommendations and supporting arguments regarding the<br />

implementation of default Critical Peak Pricing (CPP) rates for large customers.<br />

INTRODUCTION<br />

This Proceeding was predicated on regulator concerns stated in ACR<br />

02-06-001, “…that during the summer of 2005 there may be insufficient<br />

1 Administrative Law Judge’s Ruling Setting Prehearing Conference and Addressing Procedural Issues<br />

(February 1, 2005), page 4.<br />

- 2 -


generating capacity to meet system peak demand 2 ”. The ACR further<br />

expressed concern that existing demand programs do not provide a rational way<br />

to plan to serve an anticipated, ongoing supply shortage. The ACR ordered<br />

Pacific Gas and Electric (PG&E), Southern California Edison (SCE) and San<br />

Diego Gas and Electric (SDG&E) to file proposals for new default rate schedules<br />

for all customers over 200KW demand that provide strong peak demand signals<br />

while also preserving class revenue neutrality. The ACR further described the<br />

overall goal of the required filing as follows: “Our goal in directing the filing of<br />

applications for a new default rate structure is to provide sufficient economic<br />

incentive to large customers to predictably and systematically move their usage<br />

out of the critical peak period, and if they do not do so, have them pay an<br />

increased rate for usage during that narrow set of hours”.<br />

Responding to the ACR, the three utilities filed Critical Peak Pricing<br />

Applications which included various combinations of critical peak period charges,<br />

credits for usage during non critical peak periods, and hedging premiums for<br />

customers wishing to opt out of the CPP program. The Office of Ratepayer<br />

Advocates (ORA) also submitted a proposal for imposing CPP tariffs.<br />

Responding to a request from the Presiding ALJ, the three utilities also provided<br />

some analyses of the bill impacts of their proposals. ORA did not provide similar<br />

information claiming lack of customer data on which to perform the analysis.<br />

Testimony responding to these proposals has been filed in this Proceeding by<br />

the California Independent System Operator (ISO) and 16 other Parties<br />

2 Assigned Commissioner and Administrative Law Judge’s Ruling Directing the Filing of Rate Design<br />

Proposals for Large Customers (December 8, 2004), page 1.<br />

- 3 -


epresenting various end use customers and customer associations. Consistent<br />

with the record that has been established in this Proceeding, <strong>BOMA</strong> <strong>SF</strong> and<br />

<strong>BOMA</strong> Cal offer the following conclusions and recommendations:<br />

Conclusion 1- A Summer 2005 Capacity Shortage is Unlikely<br />

Recommendations:<br />

1A - Stay the course – develop voluntary demand response<br />

programs<br />

1B - Resolve regulatory issues that impede infrastructure<br />

development<br />

Conclusion 2 - CPP tariffs will not reduce summer 2005 peak demand<br />

Recommendations:<br />

2A - Expand and refine existing demand response programs<br />

2B - Revise Rule 18<br />

Conclusion 3 - CPP tariffs distort cost signals<br />

Recommendations:<br />

3A – Re-establish cost of service ratemaking principles<br />

3B – Make non cost based rates voluntary<br />

3C - Begin implementing market based real time pricing<br />

Conclusion 4 - CPP tariffs discriminate against office buildings<br />

Recommendation:<br />

4 - Avoid policies that target end uses<br />

Conclusion 5 – ACR 02-06-001 amplifies regulatory uncertainty<br />

Recommendation:<br />

5 – Return to fundamental cost of service rate policies<br />

Explanations and supporting arguments for these conclusions and<br />

recommendations are provided below.<br />

CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS<br />

Conclusion 1- A Summer 2005 Capacity Shortage is Unlikely<br />

The fundamental ACR 02-06-001motivating concern, that there may be<br />

insufficient generating capacity to meet summer 2005 system peak demand, has<br />

- 4 -


not been corroborated in this proceeding. To the contrary, PG&E Witness<br />

Alvarez testified that “Northern California reserves are expected to exceed<br />

required operating reserve levels in summer 2005 and for several years after,<br />

even under extreme hot weather conditions” (Exhibit 1, page 2-2). Neither SCE<br />

nor SDG&E offered evidence of an impending summer 2005 capacity crisis for<br />

Southern California. However, ISO Witness Perez, in arguing for continuation of<br />

interruptible programs, testified that, “The CAISO shares the Commission’s<br />

‘substantial interest’ that capacity margins in California will be tight for summer<br />

2005” (Exhibit 215, page 3). In his Rebuttal Testimony, Witness Perez (with<br />

regard to Southern California), made reference to a CEC presentation entitled<br />

California’s Energy Situation: Summer 2005 (February 22, 2005) that he<br />

suggested, “continued to find a potential deficiency of approximately 1966 MW’s<br />

for September 2005”, (Exhibit 216, page 3). However, an examination of the<br />

CEC presentation (slide # 7) reveals that the deficiency referenced by Mr. Perez<br />

is a deficiency in maintaining the targeted 7% reserve margin, which is only<br />

expected to occur under 1-in-10 hot summer conditions. In conclusion, the<br />

record does not support the assumption of an impending capacity crisis for<br />

summer 2005 that might rationalize such drastic emergency measures as the<br />

imposition of hastily designed mandatory CPP tariffs.<br />

Recommendations:<br />

1A - Stay the Course - Develop Voluntary Demand Response<br />

Programs<br />

<strong>BOMA</strong> <strong>SF</strong> and <strong>BOMA</strong> Cal support PG&E’s preferred recommendation to<br />

“stay the course” in summer 2005 with existing demand response programs<br />

- 5 -


(Exhibit 1, pages 1-1 through 1-11). The Commission should focus on<br />

strengthening voluntary programs through enhanced (but cost effective) benefits<br />

for participation.<br />

1B – Resolve Regulatory Issues That Impede Infrastructure<br />

Development<br />

The fact that ACR 02-06-001 was issued on the expressed concern about<br />

insufficient generating capacity is stark testimony to the fact that regulatory<br />

uncertainty continues to impede needed investment in California’s generation<br />

and transmission infrastructure, four years after the great California Energy<br />

Crisis. Demand management can help reduce California’s need for expanded<br />

infrastructure but it can not do it all. Investment in generation and transmission<br />

will be necessary to support a growing California economy. Therefore, <strong>BOMA</strong><br />

<strong>SF</strong> and <strong>BOMA</strong> Cal strongly urge the Commission and the Legislature to<br />

accelerate efforts in resolving remaining issues of energy policy and market<br />

structure so that investment is encouraged, and unnecessary emergencies can<br />

be avoided.<br />

Conclusion 2 - CPP Tariffs Will Not Reduce Summer 2005 Peak Demand<br />

While the goal of ACR 02-06-001 was the reduction of summer 2005 peak<br />

demand, all but one CPP proposal was silent on declaring the level of 2005 peak<br />

demand reductions that were expected from the proposed CPP tariff. Only<br />

SDG&E offered an estimate (20-28 MW) and that estimate was not supported by<br />

anything more than a statement that a consultant’s model (CRA) had been used<br />

to estimate the potential demand reductions from the default CPP (Exhibit 9,<br />

- 6 -


page JM-6). While SDG&E did what they could to provide some estimate, it must<br />

be recognized that there is virtually no relevant data sample available to provide<br />

a basis for verifying the applicability of the CRA model to measuring the impact of<br />

the SDG&E default CPP tariff. As a foundation for rational policy, this estimate<br />

must be considered as little more than a shot in the dark.<br />

SCE included a description of an after the fact econometric study to<br />

estimate the impact of their CPP tariff but did not venture a forecast.<br />

PG&E also did not offer any specific demand savings estimates. This fact<br />

was acknowledged by PG&E Witness Bell in his cross-examination testimony. In<br />

his response to a question by Ms Woo, Mr. Bell stated, “Several parties have<br />

noted that PG&E has not provided a forecast of how much CPP response would<br />

result from – if our proposal were adopted. I don’t know how many customers<br />

would opt out. I don’t know how customers would respond, how those customers<br />

that did not opt out would actually respond to the new prices” (Transcript ,<br />

February 25, page 167). He then went on to speculate an upper bound of 100<br />

MW savings based on multiple assumptions, but did not provide a forecast.<br />

ORA also offered a CPP tariff proposal, but ORA did not provide any<br />

estimates of the demand savings that their proposal might achieve. In fact, ORA<br />

Witnesses Ross and Liang-Uejio, under cross examination from Mr. McCrea,<br />

revealed that the ORA proposal was not designed to meet demand reduction<br />

objectives but was designed to send an efficient price signal (Transcript,<br />

February 25, pages 96-100).<br />

- 7 -


While the record shows no credible estimates of summer 2005 peak<br />

demand savings that might result from the imposition of mandatory CPP tariffs,<br />

the record is replete with testimony from various end users and end user<br />

associations that explain why the customers that they represent could not<br />

significantly adjust their summer 2005 demand (<strong>BOMA</strong>, CLECA, CMTA, EPUC,<br />

BART, Walmart, J.C. Penny, Costco, CLFP, WPTF, ICP, CCEA, CIPA /COPE<br />

and CFBF). The primary reasons given were, first that end users have already<br />

made investments, adopted efficient energy practices, and have few remaining<br />

options for reducing demand. And, second, it takes too long to develop<br />

investment justifications, get budget approval, and accomplish physical<br />

implementation for additional demand savings to be realized by summer 2005.<br />

In summary, the logical conclusion to reach from this record is that the imposition<br />

of CPP tariffs will not be useful in pursuing the ACR 02-06-001 goal of reducing<br />

summer 2005 peak demand.<br />

Recommendations:<br />

2A - Expand and Refine Existing Demand Response Programs<br />

The Commission should preserve, refine and expand existing interruptible<br />

and other demand response programs as proposed by PG&E in its stay the<br />

course recommendation. The Commission should also make an aggressive<br />

effort to identify smaller office buildings that have not yet adopted efficient energy<br />

practices and tailor technical support, rebates and financing plans to encourage<br />

greater energy efficiency.<br />

- 8 -


2B - Revise Rule 18<br />

CPUC Rule 18 currently prevents commercial building owners from sub<br />

metering tenant electricity usage and billing tenants in accordance with<br />

measured usage. As was mentioned in <strong>BOMA</strong> <strong>SF</strong>’s Opening Testimony (Exhibit<br />

210, page 8), this Rule shields tenants from TOU price signals and hampers the<br />

realization of the energy efficiency benefits that such signals can be expected to<br />

produce. Modification of Rule 18 may be one of the simplest and cost effective<br />

ways of obtaining additional energy efficiency savings. This issue is being<br />

considered in Proceeding 04-08-038.<br />

Conclusion 3 - CPP Tariffs Distort Cost Signals<br />

CPP tariffs further distort the cost signals in TOU electricity prices. The current<br />

TOU rate schedules were thrown out of alignment with cost of service in 2001<br />

when most of the energy crisis costs were piled onto the commercial and<br />

industrial rate classes, and most heavily on the summer peak periods, without<br />

any attempt at cost of service justification. This was explained by PG&E Witness<br />

Bell during cross examination by Ms. Hasbrouck as follows:<br />

“Our on-peak rates for the Schedule E-19 and E-20 customers were nearly doubled in 2001 by<br />

the surcharges that were applied then and were applied in a proceeding that was conducted<br />

under a very short time line, rather like this one, and there was no cost basis to how those<br />

were added into the rates. We're trying to work them down over time. But, as a result, if you<br />

look at the rates that applied to on-peak service now, I don't think that you can say anything about<br />

them being cost-based. They are tariffs that were originally set before the rate freeze back in our<br />

1996 general rate case and were held fixed for a period of five or six years, and then we had what<br />

was referred to as the 3-cent rate increase adopted in 2001 that was actually more like 4, 4-1/2<br />

cents for these customers, and it wasn't applied on an equal-cents-per-kilowatt-hour basis, it was<br />

heavily tilted towards the on-peak period, and there wasn't a cost basis for how it was tilted<br />

toward the on-peak period. There was some hope that it would create a new price signal for the<br />

summer of 2001, but people were working around the clock to try and make the new rates work<br />

across Edison and PG&E -- I don't think that San Diego was part of that case, but it was really a<br />

case very similar to this one, and I think we created a lot of unintended consequences; and I<br />

- 9 -


don't think that our current on-peak rates have any relationship to costs right now”<br />

(Transcript, February 25, page 174)(emphasis added)..<br />

Now the CPP rates add additional charges on those schedules and peak rate<br />

periods, again without cost of service justification. While the utilities have tried to<br />

quickly design ACR 02-06-001 mandated tariffs there has been very little attempt<br />

to justify these tariffs as being cost based. ORA registered attempts at arguing<br />

that their CPP price signals are cost based while ignoring the current<br />

misalignment of commercial and industrial rates from cost of service. In<br />

conclusion, current commercial and industrial rates are not cost justified and<br />

possess neither the properties of efficient price signals nor of equitable service<br />

cost allocation factors.<br />

Recommendations:<br />

3A – Re-establish Cost of Service Ratemaking Principles<br />

The implications of electricity price distortions from true cost of service are<br />

both inequitable assignment of costs across customers and inefficient<br />

consumption of electricity. Both of these implications also imply drags on the<br />

productive operation and growth of the California economy. The CPUC is<br />

arguably the most significant economic policy entity in the state, and it is<br />

important for economic recovery that the CPUC move immediately to re-establish<br />

cost of service ratemaking principles and correct the damage caused by past<br />

policy decisions. <strong>BOMA</strong> <strong>SF</strong> and <strong>BOMA</strong> Cal urge the CPUC to seriously consider<br />

the many pleas for a cost of service basis in electric rates that have emerged in<br />

this Proceeding.<br />

- 10 -


3B – Make Non-Cost Based Rates Voluntary<br />

Cost of service principles have been the foundation for electricity<br />

regulation in the United States for many decades, so much so that non cost<br />

based rates are not generally accepted by ratepayers as legitimate. That has<br />

certainly been born out in this Proceeding. The overwhelming majority of Parties<br />

have questioned, or made references to, the cost of service basis of CPP rates.<br />

While a cost of service basis is essential for default rates, there may be<br />

legitimate reasons to provide optional rates that are designed to promote<br />

administrative objectives that are not consistent with service costs. Such rates<br />

should only be offered to ratepayers as voluntary options. This includes any<br />

version of CPP rates that the Commission may wish to retain.<br />

3C - Begin Implementing Market Based Real Time Pricing<br />

<strong>BOMA</strong> <strong>SF</strong> and <strong>BOMA</strong> Cal urge the Commission to transform its interest in<br />

dynamic pricing into the design and implementation of market based real time<br />

electricity pricing for all bundled utility customers. We believe that modern<br />

metering and communications technologies make universal real time electricity<br />

pricing both feasible and in the public interest. In contrast to CPP (which is not<br />

cost based, is discriminatory, and distorts efficient prices), market based real<br />

time pricing provides a true cost foundation for electricity pricing and the most<br />

equitable means of allocating electricity commodity costs across all utility<br />

customers. Market based real time pricing also provides the most efficient price<br />

signals for guiding energy consumption decisions and for evaluating public<br />

efficiency and demand management programs.<br />

- 11 -


With the ISO’s new market implementation on the horizon, It is time to<br />

begin taking retail electricity commodity pricing out of the contentious and<br />

politically charged hearing room, and allow prices to be resolved by the impartial<br />

wholesale markets. It is our view that every utility customer should have the right<br />

to receive timely information about the costs of the power that he or she is<br />

consuming and to manage their power costs as they choose. Today, the<br />

provision of such information should be as much a part of the electric system<br />

infrastructure as are hookups and meters. Armed with timely, accurate<br />

information, consumer’s independent decisions will yield an efficient, demand<br />

responsive electricity market to the joint benefit of all consumers.<br />

Conclusion 4 - CPP Tariffs Discriminate Against Office Buildings<br />

The penalty/credit structure of CPP tariffs has been designed to<br />

discriminate against the end uses of commercial office buildings on unsupported<br />

assumptions about the discretionary nature of air conditioning and lighting load,<br />

and about the impact of peaky daily load shapes on peak demand growth.<br />

Numerous references in the testimony of the parties, hearing transcripts, and<br />

even the ACR, appear to assign blame for California’s peak demand growth on<br />

consumers with peaky daily load shapes that are the result of their discretionary<br />

air conditioning and lighting end uses (particularly commercial office buildings).<br />

For example, the ACR states the following: “Customers between 200 and 500<br />

KW may have more air conditioning load, and their class load profiles generally<br />

- 12 -


align more closely with the system peak than the largest customers, so they may<br />

have more load capable of shifting off the critical peak” (ACR, page 4).<br />

In his cross examination by Mr. Yates, PG&E Witness Mayers explicitly<br />

mentioned targeting office buildings as follows: “What we try to do is we tried to,<br />

as best we could, minimize the impact on customers taking into effect the<br />

processing and manufacturing. In fact, we -- we followed the suggestion in the<br />

ACR which suggested that between 200 and 500 kW generally air-conditioning<br />

load is more prevalent and more discretionally -- discretionary load is available<br />

for those customers, and that's on a general matter there's nothing in those rates<br />

to differentiate a manufacturing customer from, say, a -- an office building, for<br />

instance “(Transcript, February 25, page 140).<br />

Using these same unsupported assumptions about air conditioning and<br />

load shapes, representatives of industrial, agricultural and other energy users<br />

have attempted to deflect the application of CPP from their constituents by<br />

arguing that the flat or inverted daily load shapes of their constituents do not<br />

contribute to peak demand.<br />

<strong>BOMA</strong> <strong>SF</strong> and <strong>BOMA</strong> Cal believe that the basic assumptions that lead to<br />

this discriminatory targeting of commercial office building end uses are false, and<br />

the CPP rate design that derives from those assumptions is both misguided and<br />

harmful to California business. First, air conditioning and lighting loads in<br />

commercial buildings are not discretionary. This point was made in <strong>BOMA</strong>’s<br />

Rebuttal Testimony as follows: “While often referred to as discretionary comfort<br />

and convenience services, air conditioning and lighting in commercial buildings<br />

- 13 -


are actually critical components of the services that buildings provide to support<br />

the business operations of their tenants. For both practical business productivity<br />

reasons and contractual reasons, these services must be provided within very<br />

narrow tolerances of temperature and lighting levels” (Exhibit 211, page 5).<br />

While it may be true, that some air conditioning loads for some customers<br />

are discretionary and incentive programs might be effective in reducing such<br />

usage. However, it is simply bad policy to use a broad brush assumption that all<br />

air conditioning and lighting load is discretionary and set tariffs to punish those<br />

customers who do can not or will not reduce those end use loads.<br />

The second false assumption that appears to drive the discriminatory<br />

CPP rate design is that peaky load shapes are the cause of the growth of<br />

California’s system peak demand. The fact is that the shape of daily load<br />

curves is irrelevant to peak demand growth. California’s peak demand<br />

problem is one of year to year demand growth so the only aspect of a customer’s<br />

load that is relevant to peak demand growth is the annual change in customer’s<br />

load that is coincident with the system annual peak. To examine this issue,<br />

assume that three utility customers (A, B, & C), each have demand of exactly 1<br />

MW at the time of the annual system peak (say 4:00 P.M. on August 20).<br />

Suppose also that Customer A has a peaked daily load shape that hits its peak at<br />

4:00 P.M., Customer B has a perfectly flat daily load curve that is always exactly<br />

1MW, and Customer C has an inverted daily load curve that reaches its minimum<br />

of 1 MW at 4:00 P.M. Each of the three customers account for exactly the same<br />

demand at the system peak and impose the same costs on the system.<br />

- 14 -


Whatever happens to the load levels of the three customers on either side of the<br />

peak is of no significance to peak demand or the system costs at peak demand.<br />

Thus, the only portion of the daily load shape is relevant to system peak demand<br />

and cost is the quantity of demand on the load curve that is coincident with the<br />

system peak. Furthermore, it is only the year to year growth of the single point on<br />

the daily load curve that is coincident with the next annual peak that is relevant<br />

for assigning responsibility for peak demand growth and cost. The year to year<br />

growth may be more likely to come from the customers with the flat or inverted<br />

daily load curves (from sales growth and expanded operations) than from a full<br />

occupancy commercial office building that has the same peaky load every<br />

business day of the year. A detailed discussion of the peaky but stable load<br />

curves of efficient office buildings was presented in <strong>BOMA</strong> <strong>SF</strong>’s Opening<br />

Testimony (Exhibit 210, pages 4-6). This said, there may be some office<br />

buildings that have not adopted best energy management practices such that<br />

their buildings show substantial seasonal variations in load that could be modified<br />

over time, given adequate investment. However, focusing punitive behavior<br />

modifying tariffs on all commercial buildings on the false assumption that peaky<br />

daily load shapes are the cause of system peak demand growth distracts the<br />

Commission from discovering the true nature of the problem and devising more<br />

effective policies.<br />

- 15 -


Recommendation:<br />

4 – Avoid Policies That Target End-Uses<br />

It is not the role of the Commission to decide what end uses should consume<br />

electricity and which should not. It is the role of the Commission to set just and<br />

reasonable rates that consumers factor into their own choices as to how much<br />

electricity that they will consume. Devising rate policy that discriminates for or<br />

against any end use is a slippery slope that does not have a positive outcome<br />

and should be avoided by the Commission.<br />

Conclusion 5 – ACR 02-06-001 Amplifies Regulatory Uncertainty<br />

The intent of the ACR is widely interpreted, at least by commercial building<br />

owners, as one of designing punitive rates to force consumers to modify their<br />

behavior in a manner that suits administrative goals. Both the stated goal of the<br />

ACR and the CPP tariff structures that the utilities have developed in response to<br />

the ACR lend support to that interpretation.<br />

The ACR also rekindles fears of another capacity shortage four years after<br />

the energy crisis, and puts focus on the failures of California policy makers to<br />

resolve the policy issues that continue to hinder the development of an<br />

infrastructure that would provide adequate capacity. For both of the above<br />

reasons, the ACR has significantly increased business uncertainty about the<br />

productivity, rationality, fairness, and stability of CPUC. This increased<br />

uncertainty will undoubtedly have a dampening impact on business investment in<br />

- 16 -


California at a time when the economy is struggling to pull out of the worst<br />

recession in decades.<br />

Recommendation:<br />

5 – Return to Fundamental Cost of Service Rate Policies<br />

The best outcome of this Proceeding is for the Commission to reject all of<br />

the CPP Applications, to reaffirm a commitment to cost of service ratemaking<br />

principles, and to begin the development of plans for the implementation of<br />

universal market based real time pricing.<br />

<strong>BOMA</strong> San Francisco and <strong>BOMA</strong> California appreciate the opportunity<br />

to provide this input to the Commission.<br />

Respectfully submitted,<br />

Bill F. Roberts<br />

President<br />

Economic Sciences Corporation<br />

1516 LeRoy Avenue<br />

Berkeley, CA 94708<br />

(510) 841-6869<br />

bill@econsci.com<br />

for:<br />

The Building Owners and Managers Association of San Francisco and,<br />

The Building Owners and Managers Association of San Francisco<br />

- 17 -


CERTIFICATE <strong>OF</strong> SERVICE<br />

I hereby certify that I have this day served a copy of the Opening Brief of<br />

the Building Owners and Managers Association of San Francisco and the<br />

Building Owners and Managers of California on all known parties of record in<br />

this proceeding by delivering four copies and one original to the CPUC’s San<br />

Francisco Docket Office and via email to all parties on the service list.<br />

Executed on March 14, 2005 at Berkeley, California.<br />

___________________<br />

Valborg T. Roberts<br />

Economic Sciences Corporation<br />

1516 LeRoy Avenue<br />

Berkeley, CA 94708<br />

(510)841-6869<br />

vali@econsci.net<br />

- 18 -

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!