11.07.2015 Views

Barriers to productivity growth in the retail sector

Barriers to productivity growth in the retail sector

Barriers to productivity growth in the retail sector

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong><strong>productivity</strong><strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong><strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rBackground report prepared for <strong>the</strong>Danish Productivity Commission8 May 2013


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rAuthors:Anders Oskar Kjøller-HansenMart<strong>in</strong> H. ThelleErik L<strong>in</strong>dén


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rTable of contents1 Employment and <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>Danish <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r 22 <strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> 82.1 <strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r 82.2 Effect of barriers 113 Case: Retail <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>in</strong> Sweden s<strong>in</strong>ce<strong>the</strong> early 1990s 154 Economic potential of deregulation 184.2 The impact of zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK 184.3 Long term <strong>productivity</strong> ga<strong>in</strong> of 13 per cent <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> grocery<strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r 204.4 Conclusion 24References 26


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rChapter 1Employment and <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>Danish <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rRetail is one of <strong>the</strong> largest subsec<strong>to</strong>rs of <strong>the</strong> private service <strong>in</strong> Denmark. In 2011, <strong>retail</strong>accounted for six per cent of <strong>to</strong>tal gross value added <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> private service sec<strong>to</strong>r, and 14per cent of <strong>the</strong> number of hours worked, cf. figure 1.Correspond<strong>in</strong>gly poor <strong>productivity</strong> performance <strong>in</strong> <strong>retail</strong> has significant impact on <strong>the</strong>Danish economy. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>retail</strong> is <strong>the</strong> bridge between private consumers and <strong>the</strong>rest of <strong>the</strong> economy and a <strong>productivity</strong> problem <strong>in</strong> <strong>retail</strong> means that households meethigher prices than <strong>the</strong>y o<strong>the</strong>rwise would when <strong>the</strong>y go shopp<strong>in</strong>g.Figure 1 Retail share <strong>to</strong>tal private service <strong>in</strong> 2011Source:Statistics Denmark, NATE691, NAT18NEmployment <strong>in</strong> <strong>retail</strong> has <strong>in</strong>creased more than <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> private sec<strong>to</strong>r overallTotal employment <strong>in</strong> <strong>retail</strong> has <strong>in</strong>creased from 189,000 <strong>in</strong> 1995 <strong>to</strong> 236,000 <strong>in</strong> 2011 correspond<strong>in</strong>g<strong>to</strong> a 25 per cent <strong>in</strong>crease over <strong>the</strong> period, cf. figure 2. In comparison, <strong>to</strong>tal employment<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> private sec<strong>to</strong>r has <strong>in</strong>creased by 7 per cent. The correspond<strong>in</strong>g figures for<strong>to</strong>tal hours worked are 17 per cent <strong>in</strong> <strong>retail</strong> and 7 <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal private sec<strong>to</strong>r.2


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rBox 1 Data sources and measur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>productivity</strong>Productivity <strong>in</strong> this report is hourly labour <strong>productivity</strong> measured as gross value addedper hour worked. This measure does not take <strong>in</strong><strong>to</strong> account <strong>the</strong> amount of o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>putfac<strong>to</strong>rs used <strong>in</strong> production i.e. capital <strong>in</strong>puts. Preferably one would consider <strong>to</strong>tal fac<strong>to</strong>r<strong>productivity</strong> (TFP) which is a measure of how efficiently all measured <strong>in</strong>put fac<strong>to</strong>rs areused <strong>in</strong> production.For <strong>the</strong> peer group comparisons for <strong>to</strong>tal <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r <strong>productivity</strong> we use data fromtwo sources. We use national accounts data from Eurostat of gross value added atbasic prices and data on <strong>to</strong>tal hours worked. For <strong>the</strong> United States data is from <strong>the</strong> USBureau of Labor Statistics. Data from both sources span <strong>the</strong> period from 1995-2010.Source:For <strong>the</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> development <strong>in</strong> <strong>retail</strong> subsec<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>in</strong> Denmark we use national accountsdata from Statistics Denmark on gross value added and <strong>to</strong>tal hours worked bysubsec<strong>to</strong>r. This data spans <strong>the</strong> period from 1995-2007. Likewise employment data for<strong>retail</strong> subsec<strong>to</strong>rs are from Statistics Denmark.Statistics Denmark, Eurostat National Accounts, <strong>the</strong> Danish Productivity Commission, US Bureau ofLabor StatisticsFigure 2 Employment <strong>in</strong> <strong>retail</strong> has <strong>in</strong>creased substantially s<strong>in</strong>ce<strong>the</strong> mid-1990s and only decl<strong>in</strong>ed slightly dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> downturnThousand260240220200180160140120189+25%2361001995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011Source:Statistics Denmark, NAT18N.The <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r is diverse and can be analysed <strong>in</strong> five different subsec<strong>to</strong>rsThe <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r is highly heterogeneous s<strong>in</strong>ce it is composed of all s<strong>to</strong>res that sell productsdirectly <strong>to</strong> private households. The <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r is composed by everyth<strong>in</strong>g fromsmall corner s<strong>to</strong>res (kiosks) <strong>to</strong> large specialized warehouses such as IKEA and Elgiganten,as well as highly regulated subsec<strong>to</strong>rs such as pharmacies. The <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r can be analysedas five different subsec<strong>to</strong>rs, cf. figure 3. Divid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>retail</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> five subsec<strong>to</strong>rs revealsthat:3


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rThe subsec<strong>to</strong>r “o<strong>the</strong>rs and repairs” is <strong>the</strong> largest <strong>in</strong> terms of value added and <strong>to</strong>talhours worked account<strong>in</strong>g for 43 per cent of <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal of both value added and <strong>to</strong>talhours worked. This subsec<strong>to</strong>r is composed of s<strong>to</strong>res such as Harald Nyborg, IKEAand Top Toy.With regards <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> number of employees, <strong>the</strong> “grocery” subsec<strong>to</strong>r is larger than“o<strong>the</strong>rs and repairs” account<strong>in</strong>g for 35 per cent of <strong>the</strong> number of employees. Thissuggests that <strong>the</strong> number of part time employees is large <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> “grocery” subsec<strong>to</strong>r.The “grocery” subsec<strong>to</strong>r accounts for 24 per cent of <strong>to</strong>tal valued added and 27 percen<strong>to</strong>f <strong>to</strong>tal hours worked.“Pharmacies” is <strong>the</strong> smallest of <strong>the</strong> subsec<strong>to</strong>rs and account for 7 per cent of <strong>to</strong>talvalued added <strong>in</strong> <strong>retail</strong> and 5 per cent of <strong>to</strong>tal hours worked suggest<strong>in</strong>g that labour<strong>productivity</strong> is higher <strong>in</strong> pharmacies compared <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> average <strong>in</strong> <strong>retail</strong>. This mayamong o<strong>the</strong>r th<strong>in</strong>gs reflect economic rents created by <strong>the</strong> quantity restriction regard<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> number of pharmacies.Figure 3 Retail can be divided <strong>in</strong><strong>to</strong> five subsec<strong>to</strong>rsNote: Totals are 2011 figures. Shares of <strong>to</strong>tal are based on latest available data (2007).Source: Statistics Denmark, NAT07, NAT18, McK<strong>in</strong>sey (2010)Productivity <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Danish <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r has developed poorly compared <strong>to</strong>peer countries s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> middle of <strong>the</strong> 1990sFrom 1995 <strong>to</strong> 2010, Denmark has performed significantly worse on <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong>than peer countries. In fact average annual <strong>retail</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> Denmark was 1.5percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts below a peer group average consist<strong>in</strong>g of Germany, <strong>the</strong> Ne<strong>the</strong>rlandsand Sweden, cf. figure 4. Look<strong>in</strong>g at peer countries <strong>in</strong>dividually Sweden was <strong>the</strong> best perform<strong>in</strong>gcountry <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> group with an average annual <strong>growth</strong> rate of 3.94%.4


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rFigure 4 Productivity <strong>growth</strong> relative <strong>to</strong> peer group, 1995-20104,50%4,00%3,94%3,50%3,20%3,00%2,50%2,00%1,97%1,71%1,50%1,00%0,50%0,45%1.52%0,26%0,00%DenmarkPeer groupaverageGermany Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands United States SwedenNote:Source:Peer group consists of SWE, NLD, GER. Data covers NACE classification G47 “Retail trade, except ofmo<strong>to</strong>r vehicles and mo<strong>to</strong>rcycles”.Eurostat National Accounts, <strong>the</strong> Danish Productivity Commission, US Bureau of Labor StatisticsLarge differences <strong>in</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> performance across subsec<strong>to</strong>rsBetween subsec<strong>to</strong>rs with<strong>in</strong> <strong>retail</strong> <strong>in</strong> Denmark <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> also differed dramatically.From 1995-2007 (latest year with detailed subsec<strong>to</strong>r data) <strong>the</strong> grocery subsec<strong>to</strong>r sawdecl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g labour <strong>productivity</strong> of negative 1.4 per cent per year on average, while departments<strong>to</strong>res experienced large positive <strong>growth</strong> rates. The rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g subsec<strong>to</strong>rs “Pharmacies”,“Clo<strong>the</strong>s, shoes, etc.” and “O<strong>the</strong>rs” experienced <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> rates between2.2 and 4.1 per cent per year, cf. figure 5.The pharmacy subsec<strong>to</strong>r is different from <strong>the</strong> rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g subsec<strong>to</strong>rs as it is subject <strong>to</strong> aquantity restriction set by <strong>the</strong> Danish M<strong>in</strong>istry of Health. In recent years it has been anobjective <strong>to</strong> achieve scale efficiencies <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r and hence reduce <strong>the</strong> number of pharmacies.S<strong>in</strong>ce 1995 <strong>the</strong> number of pharmacies has decreased from 337 <strong>to</strong> 316 1 while <strong>the</strong>number of packages of prescription drugs sold has <strong>in</strong>creased from 40m <strong>to</strong> 58m <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>ga substantial rise <strong>in</strong> demand that have contributed <strong>to</strong> high <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> 2 .1 Danmarks Apotekerforen<strong>in</strong>g (2001) p. 23 and Danmarks Apotekerforen<strong>in</strong>g (2012) p. 822 Danmarks Apotekerforen<strong>in</strong>g (2002) p. 20 and Danmarks Apotekerforen<strong>in</strong>g (2012) p. 735


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rFigure 5 Real <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> by subsec<strong>to</strong>r, 1995-20075%4%4,5%4,1%3%2%1%1,4%2,6%2,2%0%-1%-2%Retail Grocery Departments<strong>to</strong>res-1,4%Pharmacies Clo<strong>the</strong>s O<strong>the</strong>rsNote:Source:CAGR <strong>in</strong> GVA per hourStatistics Denmark, NAT07, NAT18.In <strong>the</strong> period from 1995 <strong>to</strong> 2007 overall <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r grew by 0.89 percent per year on average while it grew 2.37 per cent on average <strong>in</strong> peer countries, cf. figure6. Productivity <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> period from 1995-2010 was only 0.45 per cent reflect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>poor <strong>productivity</strong> performance s<strong>in</strong>ce 2007. Tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong><strong>to</strong> account <strong>the</strong> size of subsec<strong>to</strong>rs anddecompos<strong>in</strong>g <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong><strong>to</strong> contributions from subsec<strong>to</strong>rs shows that: Grocery has due <strong>to</strong> its size and negative <strong>productivity</strong> development contributednegatively by 1.2 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>to</strong> overall <strong>retail</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong>. The large category “o<strong>the</strong>rs” have contributed with positive 1.4 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts. While pharmacies have seen <strong>productivity</strong> grow by 4.1 per cent on average per yearits <strong>growth</strong> contribution is only 0.3 due <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> relatively low number of hoursworked compared <strong>to</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal <strong>retail</strong>.6


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rFigure 6 Decomposition of <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong>, 1995-20073,00%2,50%2,00%1,50%Pharmacies; 0,3%Department s<strong>to</strong>res;0,3%Clo<strong>the</strong>s, shoes etc.;0,5%Peergroup:2.4%1,00%0,50%0,00%O<strong>the</strong>rs; 1,4%DKRetail1.4 %-0,50%-1,00%-1,50%Grocery; -1,2%Source:Statistics Denmark, NAT07, NAT18, Eurostat National Accounts7


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rChapter 2<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong>One explanation for slow <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Danish <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r can be regula<strong>to</strong>rybarriers, and while <strong>the</strong>re are certa<strong>in</strong>ly o<strong>the</strong>r barriers and reasons for slow <strong>productivity</strong><strong>growth</strong>, regula<strong>to</strong>ry barriers is <strong>the</strong> focus of this report.Regula<strong>to</strong>ry barriers can limit entry and <strong>the</strong>reby reduce competition <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r. Suchimpediments <strong>to</strong> competition can reduce <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centive <strong>to</strong> cont<strong>in</strong>ually reduce costs, e.g. <strong>in</strong>order <strong>to</strong> ga<strong>in</strong> competitive advantage or by hav<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>efficient bus<strong>in</strong>esses replaced by efficientbus<strong>in</strong>esses.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, regulation can lead <strong>to</strong> unnecessary costs and <strong>the</strong>reby reduce <strong>productivity</strong>.In this chapter we identify some important barriers that may affect <strong>productivity</strong> development<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Danish <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r and draw on <strong>the</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> experience of Europeanpeer countries <strong>to</strong> estimate <strong>the</strong> potential effect of reduc<strong>in</strong>g barriers <strong>in</strong> Denmark.2.1 <strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rWhile many aspects of <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r are regulated, a ma<strong>in</strong> law govern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r is<strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation. Generally it determ<strong>in</strong>es <strong>the</strong> size and location of new s<strong>to</strong>res, cf. box2. Its importance as a barrier <strong>to</strong> competition and <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> is recently discussed<strong>in</strong> several publications. 3Moreover, <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g law is exemplified by <strong>the</strong> fact that all <strong>the</strong> 32 Føtexs<strong>to</strong>res built between 2000 and 2010 have been at <strong>the</strong> size limit. 4 In this way it may beuseful <strong>to</strong> consider regula<strong>to</strong>ry barriers <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> that are related <strong>to</strong> economiesof scale alone and treat those that have o<strong>the</strong>r effects on <strong>productivity</strong> separately, cf. figure7. Specifically <strong>in</strong> chapter 4, we quantify <strong>the</strong> economic impact of a central barrier that has<strong>to</strong> do with scale i.e. zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation.3 ØEM (2009), McK<strong>in</strong>sey (2010), Konkurrencestyrelsen (2011).4 McK<strong>in</strong>sey (2010) p. 140.8


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rFigure 7 Productivity potential by outlet sizeSource:Copenhagen EconomicsA long list of barriers exists that are specific <strong>to</strong> subsec<strong>to</strong>rs with<strong>in</strong> <strong>retail</strong>, cf. table 1. Onesuch example is <strong>the</strong> license requirement <strong>to</strong> own and operate a pharmacy. This licenserequirement restricts entry and is a typical example of a rent creat<strong>in</strong>g barrier. Ano<strong>the</strong>rexample is <strong>the</strong> restriction on condition<strong>in</strong>g <strong>retail</strong> sale of fuels on sales of o<strong>the</strong>r products.Table 1 provides an overview of regula<strong>to</strong>ry barriers categorised <strong>in</strong> <strong>to</strong> regulation whichaffect scale (zon<strong>in</strong>g law) and regulation which have o<strong>the</strong>r effects (non-scale).Table 1 Overview of regula<strong>to</strong>ry barriers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Danish <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rBarrierScaleTypeSubsec<strong>to</strong>rsaffectedOutlet size Scale All outlets c, eLocation Scale All outlets eNon-scaleBan on condition<strong>in</strong>g<strong>retail</strong> sale of fuelswith sale of o<strong>the</strong>rproduct categoriesMo<strong>to</strong>r fuelsQuantity regulation License Pharmacies eLocation License Pharmacies eLicense <strong>to</strong> operate License Pharmacies eRegulation onpricesRequired publicationof wholesalerebatesPrice Pharmacies cMarket<strong>in</strong>gPharmaciesEconomictype[Entry (e ),cost (c ),discrim<strong>in</strong>a<strong>to</strong>ry(d)]ccEconomic effectRestrict domestic competitionand <strong>in</strong>ternational entry, andh<strong>in</strong>der economies of scaleeffectsEntry barrier, reduce access<strong>to</strong> s<strong>to</strong>re locations and hencecompetitionRestrict<strong>in</strong>g retaliers leewayand affect<strong>in</strong>g development ofcisions on franchise conceptsLess competition result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>higher consumer pricesLess competition result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>higher consumer pricesBarrier <strong>to</strong> entry reduce competitionReduces competition amongpharmacies, and may harmconsumer pricesConscious parallellism amongdistribu<strong>to</strong>rs affect<strong>in</strong>g pricesett<strong>in</strong>gSourcePlanlovenPlanlovenMarket<strong>in</strong>gBenz<strong>in</strong>forhandlerkontraktlovenApotekerLovenApotekerLovenApotekerLovenApotekerLovenLægemiddelloven9


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rRegulations onprices and feesFixed pricesBan on advertis<strong>in</strong>gInternationalUneven legislationconcern<strong>in</strong>g foodacross EU countriesUneven regulationregard<strong>in</strong>g labell<strong>in</strong>gacross <strong>the</strong> EUNote:Source:Price Pr<strong>in</strong>tet media cPriceB<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g resale prices limitscompetitionCoverment regulated prices restricts competitionMarket<strong>in</strong>gTobaccoproductsTobaccoproductsProduct Grocery e,dMarket<strong>in</strong>gAll outlets(ma<strong>in</strong>ly foodand personalcare products)cce,dLimit consumer behaviour and competitionLimits competition from <strong>in</strong>ternational distribu<strong>to</strong>rsand <strong>retail</strong>ers with established distributionchannelsUneven labell<strong>in</strong>g about products ethical andbeneficial characteristics restricts competitionbetween goods and <strong>in</strong>crease consumer <strong>in</strong>formationcosts1 Nordic competition authorities (2005) – Nordic Food Market, a taste for competition p.110Planloven, Apotekerloven, Konkurrencestyrelsen (2011), Detailhandelsforum (2012), Mck<strong>in</strong>sey(2010), ProduktivitetskommissionenAs a supplement <strong>to</strong> table 1 it is important <strong>to</strong> mention regulation on open<strong>in</strong>g hours. S<strong>in</strong>ce2000, laws regulat<strong>in</strong>g open<strong>in</strong>g hours have gradually been liberalised and <strong>in</strong> Oc<strong>to</strong>ber 2012<strong>the</strong> law was changed so that now <strong>the</strong>re are no restrictions on open<strong>in</strong>g hours besides onpublic holidays. While this regula<strong>to</strong>ry barrier has now been removed it has had an effec<strong>to</strong>n <strong>productivity</strong> his<strong>to</strong>rically and may expla<strong>in</strong> some of <strong>the</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> gap presented <strong>in</strong>chapter 1.Box 2 Zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation <strong>in</strong> Denmark (Planloven)The Danish zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation with regards <strong>to</strong> <strong>retail</strong> has <strong>the</strong> purpose <strong>to</strong> secure a variedassortment of s<strong>to</strong>res <strong>in</strong> smaller, medium sized cities as well as <strong>in</strong> each district <strong>in</strong> largercities. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore an objective is <strong>to</strong> ensure that s<strong>to</strong>res are setup <strong>in</strong> places with accessfor all types of road users especially pedestrians, bikes and public transportation<strong>in</strong> order <strong>to</strong> secure a susta<strong>in</strong>able <strong>retail</strong> structure with limited distances <strong>to</strong> shopp<strong>in</strong>gpo<strong>in</strong>ts.Generally <strong>the</strong> law regulates <strong>the</strong> possible location as well as <strong>the</strong> size of new s<strong>to</strong>res. Thelaw caps <strong>the</strong> s<strong>to</strong>re size at 3500m2 for grocery markets, and 2000m2 for o<strong>the</strong>r s<strong>to</strong>res.In smaller cities and communities (population smaller than 40.000) <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal floorspace for <strong>retail</strong> purposes is capped as well.Generally this has two effects. The first is on entry and exit due <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> regulation onlocation, which limits competition <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r. Second is <strong>the</strong> ability of s<strong>to</strong>res <strong>to</strong>achieve scale effects due <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> cap on s<strong>to</strong>re size.Source: Bekendtgørelse af lov om planlægn<strong>in</strong>g (Planloven), kapitel 2d.Summary of regula<strong>to</strong>ry barriersAs presented <strong>in</strong> table 1 each subsec<strong>to</strong>r is regulated by different types of barriers. All sec<strong>to</strong>rsare for <strong>in</strong>stance affected by zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation, while only pharmacies are subject <strong>to</strong>license requirements, cf. figure 8. While some products that are sold <strong>in</strong> supermarkets,department s<strong>to</strong>res and “o<strong>the</strong>r” outlets are subject <strong>to</strong> market<strong>in</strong>g and product regulation,for <strong>in</strong>stance <strong>to</strong>bacco products, <strong>the</strong> grocery subsec<strong>to</strong>r is highlighted because its ma<strong>in</strong> productfoods face uneven regulation across <strong>the</strong> EU which affects competition from foreigncompanies.10


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rFigure 8 Summary of barriers by sec<strong>to</strong>rSource:Planloven, Apotekerloven, Konkurrencestyrelsen (2011), Detailhandelsforum (2012), Mck<strong>in</strong>sey(2010), Produktivitetskommissionen2.2 Effect of barriersThe barriers identified <strong>in</strong> section 2.1 can be categorized <strong>in</strong><strong>to</strong> five different types accord<strong>in</strong>g<strong>to</strong> how <strong>the</strong>y affect <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r, cf. figure 8:Scale (e.g. zon<strong>in</strong>g law)License (e.g. pharmacist are required <strong>to</strong> have a license <strong>to</strong> operate)Market<strong>in</strong>g (e.g. restrictions on condition<strong>in</strong>g sale of fuels with o<strong>the</strong>r goods)Price (e.g. b<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g resale prices on pr<strong>in</strong>ted media)Product (e.g. food product regulation is uneven across <strong>the</strong> EU)11


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rFigure 9 Regulation have different effects on <strong>productivity</strong>Source:Planloven, Apotekerloven, Konkurrencestyrelsen (2011), Detailhandelsforum (2012), McK<strong>in</strong>sey(2010), Produktivitetskommissionen, Copenhagen Economics.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore <strong>the</strong> economic effect of <strong>the</strong>se regula<strong>to</strong>ry barriers can be divided <strong>in</strong><strong>to</strong> threeeconomic types: Rent-creat<strong>in</strong>g: These are barriers that restrict entry and <strong>the</strong>refore create a rent for<strong>in</strong>cumbents. One example is <strong>the</strong> quantity restriction <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> pharmacy subsec<strong>to</strong>rwhich creates rent for license holders. Ano<strong>the</strong>r is zon<strong>in</strong>g law which restricts <strong>the</strong>access <strong>to</strong> good locations for <strong>retail</strong>ers creat<strong>in</strong>g rent for <strong>in</strong>cumbent s<strong>to</strong>res. Cost-creat<strong>in</strong>g: These barriers raise <strong>the</strong> costs of participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> market.Among o<strong>the</strong>rs <strong>the</strong> required publication of wholesale rebates <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> pharmaceuticalsmarket, <strong>the</strong> cap on s<strong>to</strong>re size <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g law, and uneven legislation on labell<strong>in</strong>gof products across <strong>the</strong> EU can be given as examples of cost-creat<strong>in</strong>g barriers. Discrim<strong>in</strong>a<strong>to</strong>ry: discrim<strong>in</strong>a<strong>to</strong>ry barriers provide some market ac<strong>to</strong>rs with an advantagecompared <strong>to</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rs. Here uneven legislation across EU countries with regards<strong>to</strong> food products and food process<strong>in</strong>g provides an example. This may makeit harder for foreign companies <strong>to</strong> compete <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Danish market.While a certa<strong>in</strong> regulation can be categorised as be<strong>in</strong>g one of <strong>the</strong>se economic types, <strong>the</strong>yneed not necessarily be mutually exclusive. For example location restrictions <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>glaw may be rent creat<strong>in</strong>g by restrict<strong>in</strong>g access <strong>to</strong> good locations, as well as cost creat<strong>in</strong>gby only allow<strong>in</strong>g entry <strong>to</strong> locations which may be suboptimal from a cost perspective.12


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rProductivity effects of zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation <strong>in</strong> DenmarkThe Danish zon<strong>in</strong>g law (planloven) is a ma<strong>in</strong> determ<strong>in</strong>ant of <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> market structure <strong>in</strong>Denmark with its limitation <strong>to</strong> location and size of new s<strong>to</strong>res, which prevents <strong>the</strong> entranceof efficient s<strong>to</strong>re formats such as hypermarkets, cf. box 1.Its importance as a barrier <strong>to</strong> competition and <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> is recently discussed<strong>in</strong> several publications 5 .The <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>in</strong>hibit<strong>in</strong>g effects of zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation <strong>in</strong>clude:Limited <strong>in</strong>troduction of efficient s<strong>to</strong>re formats that allow <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r <strong>to</strong> achieve<strong>productivity</strong> improvements through economies of scale and through competitivepressure on exist<strong>in</strong>g s<strong>to</strong>re formats.Low entry and competitive pressure due <strong>to</strong> limited access <strong>to</strong> good exist<strong>in</strong>g s<strong>to</strong>relocations as well as new locations. Limits competition of both new foreign companiesand potential domestic entrants.Little adoption of new technologies, because fixed costs of <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> IT solutionsare relatively large for smaller s<strong>to</strong>re formats. Productivity ga<strong>in</strong>s related <strong>to</strong>adoption of IT may <strong>the</strong>refore partly be held back by zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation.Deregulat<strong>in</strong>g zon<strong>in</strong>g restrictions could <strong>in</strong>volve <strong>the</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g scale improvements 6 : Ease of adm<strong>in</strong>istration of large s<strong>to</strong>res compared <strong>to</strong> many smaller ones Larger sales per costumer Eased supply management Share of space for check, adm<strong>in</strong>istration, and entrance are lower. S<strong>to</strong>res outside city centres are able <strong>to</strong> reduce supply costs More hypermarkets may improve <strong>the</strong> case for <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> IT solutions such aselectronic price tags and self-service check outs.Zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation and market structure <strong>in</strong> Denmark and SwedenAchiev<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> aforementioned improvements may contribute <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> Danish <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r. But what is <strong>the</strong> potential impact on <strong>productivity</strong> from eas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>regulation? Zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation <strong>in</strong> Denmark and Sweden generally serve <strong>the</strong> same purpose 7 ,but <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> provisions govern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r with respect <strong>to</strong> location and size of news<strong>to</strong>res <strong>the</strong> Swedish regulation leaves complete authority <strong>to</strong> local governments ra<strong>the</strong>r thanregulat<strong>in</strong>g it centrally as <strong>in</strong> Denmark. This may make it easier for <strong>retail</strong>ers <strong>to</strong> build larges<strong>to</strong>res <strong>in</strong> Sweden than <strong>in</strong> Denmark, and hence contribute <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> differences <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong>market structure between Sweden and Denmark. In Sweden each grocery s<strong>to</strong>re serves2850 people on average while <strong>the</strong> same number is 1750 <strong>in</strong> Denmark, cf. table 2.Table 2 DK has more s<strong>to</strong>res and less IT enablement than peercountriesDenmarkSweden/peer5 ØEM (2009), McK<strong>in</strong>sey (2010), Konkurrencestyrelsen (2011).6 Detailhandelsforum (2012) p. 1747 Plan- och bygglag (2010:900), Bekendtgørelse af lov om planlægn<strong>in</strong>g, nr 937 (2009).13


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rgroupPersons per grocery outlet, 2007 1724 2857Share of shoppers who visit grocery s<strong>to</strong>res more than 3 times per week 61 35Share of companies pilot<strong>in</strong>g self-service check-outs 38 77 1Share of companies with electronic price labels 13 25 2Note:1 and 2 are figures for a peer group consist<strong>in</strong>g of Belgium, F<strong>in</strong>land, France, Germany, <strong>the</strong> Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands,Sweden and <strong>the</strong> UKSource: McK<strong>in</strong>sey (2010), Detailhandelsforum (2012),Rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g barriers are important as wellMuch attention is given <strong>to</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation s<strong>in</strong>ce it is a ma<strong>in</strong> determ<strong>in</strong>ant of <strong>the</strong> overall<strong>retail</strong> market structure. Contrary <strong>the</strong> rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g identified barriers do not affect <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r<strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> same extent. The importance <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual subsec<strong>to</strong>rs should not beneglected. For example uneven regulation regard<strong>in</strong>g food products and product labell<strong>in</strong>gacross <strong>the</strong> EU may contribute <strong>to</strong> lower competitive pressure from <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>retail</strong>ers.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> limitation on <strong>the</strong> number of pharmacies <strong>in</strong> a period of ris<strong>in</strong>g demandhas contributed <strong>to</strong> more packages of prescription drugs be<strong>in</strong>g distributed by each pharmacyand hence <strong>to</strong> high <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> this sec<strong>to</strong>r.Non-regula<strong>to</strong>ry barriersNon-regula<strong>to</strong>ry barriers may also impede <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong>. These <strong>in</strong>clude market sizeand language barriers <strong>in</strong> Denmark, which may discourage large <strong>retail</strong> cha<strong>in</strong>s from enter<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> market. Regulation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> downstream supply cha<strong>in</strong> may also impede <strong>productivity</strong><strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r.14


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rChapter 3Case: Retail <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>in</strong> Swedens<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> early 1990sThe Swedish <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r has experienced high <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of<strong>the</strong> 1990s. In 1995 Sweden entered <strong>the</strong> European Union and <strong>to</strong> <strong>in</strong>tegrate Sweden <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong>new competition law and regulation of <strong>the</strong> European Union a new competition authoritywas established. The new competition authority promoted a changed behaviour amongpolicymakers <strong>in</strong> favour of more competition. 8The <strong>retail</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry has experienced a large <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> last 15 <strong>to</strong>20 years and this development is ra<strong>the</strong>r a result of a change <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> structure of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustrycaused by a de fac<strong>to</strong> “deregulation” of <strong>the</strong> market due <strong>to</strong> more favourable views oncompetition. The ma<strong>in</strong> fac<strong>to</strong>rs beh<strong>in</strong>d <strong>the</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>in</strong>crease are 9 : Intensified national-, <strong>in</strong>ternational- and potential competition. Forced <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry<strong>to</strong> become more efficient, <strong>to</strong> modernize and adopt new technology. Foreign entrants<strong>in</strong>clude Norwegian firms Elgiganten and XXL Sport och Vildmark, Germanfirms Media Markt and Lidl and Danish grocery discounter Net<strong>to</strong>. Entry- and exit processes. Unproductive firms are replaced by new highly productivefirms Economies of scope. Small private bus<strong>in</strong>esses l<strong>in</strong>k up <strong>in</strong> large cha<strong>in</strong>s and becomemore efficient, by cooperat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> purchase, distribution and market<strong>in</strong>g Economies of scale. S<strong>to</strong>res has adopted large format strategies and have becomelarger both <strong>in</strong> terms of size and numbers of products, e.g. IKEA, Elgiganten andXXL-sport och vildmark Adoption of new IT-solutions. Increase efficiency <strong>in</strong> logistics/distribution throughadoption of new <strong>in</strong>formation- and communication technology, both <strong>in</strong> delivery <strong>to</strong>s<strong>to</strong>res and <strong>to</strong> cus<strong>to</strong>mers Efficiency improvements <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> cha<strong>in</strong> of delivery. Larger firms and <strong>the</strong> concentrationof <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry have contributed <strong>to</strong> dis<strong>in</strong>termediation. Information of demandare directly affect<strong>in</strong>g production and delivery <strong>to</strong> s<strong>to</strong>res as <strong>the</strong> whole valuecha<strong>in</strong> is <strong>in</strong>-house New channels of competition. E-commerce has <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>the</strong> supply of products<strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> cus<strong>to</strong>mers, and service has become a competition <strong>to</strong>ol <strong>in</strong> s<strong>to</strong>resChanges <strong>in</strong> regulations of <strong>the</strong> Swedish <strong>retail</strong> marketBetween 1992 and 1997 Sweden saw a temporary change <strong>in</strong> legislation of <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>glaw. 10 Before 1992 <strong>the</strong> municipalities – who adm<strong>in</strong>istrate <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g- and constructionlaw <strong>in</strong> Sweden – had <strong>the</strong> possibility <strong>to</strong> oppose new more effective firms <strong>to</strong> enter <strong>the</strong> market.This possibility was used <strong>to</strong> protect <strong>the</strong> already established <strong>in</strong>dustry on <strong>the</strong> market. In1992 a change <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> legislation was made <strong>in</strong> order for plann<strong>in</strong>g <strong>to</strong> not restrict competi-8 McK<strong>in</strong>sey, 2006 pp.119-1209 Institutet för tillväxtpolitiska studier, 2006, McK<strong>in</strong>sey & Company, 2006 and Orth & Maican, 201210 McK<strong>in</strong>sey, 2006 pp. 117-11815


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rtion and <strong>the</strong> municipalities lost some of <strong>the</strong> possibility <strong>to</strong> prohibit firms <strong>to</strong> establish <strong>the</strong>irbus<strong>in</strong>esses. This <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>the</strong> competition as new productive firms entered <strong>the</strong> marketand replaced <strong>the</strong> less productive firms. In 1997 <strong>the</strong> pre-1992 legislation was re<strong>in</strong>troducedand <strong>the</strong> municipalities re-established <strong>the</strong>ir position, but <strong>the</strong> effects where now different <strong>to</strong><strong>the</strong> situation before <strong>the</strong> change <strong>in</strong> legislation. The policy makers had changed <strong>the</strong>ir behaviourand found that entry of new firms was <strong>in</strong> favour <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> municipalities, with lowerprice and higher supply of products. However, <strong>to</strong>day <strong>the</strong> land use is still regulated, and<strong>the</strong> municipalities determ<strong>in</strong>e, when, where and how large new s<strong>to</strong>res are allowed <strong>to</strong> be. 11Deregulation of pharmaceuticals. Up until 2009 <strong>the</strong> pharmaceutical market was tightlyregulated, and no entry <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> market was allowed. In 2009 <strong>the</strong> market was deregulatedand private firms entered <strong>the</strong> market. The ma<strong>in</strong> goals of <strong>the</strong> deregulation were <strong>to</strong>:oooIncrease availability of pharmaceuticalsIncrease serviceDecrease priceEffect of <strong>the</strong> deregulation so far is that <strong>the</strong> number of pharmacies has <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal,but <strong>the</strong> establishment has not <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>the</strong> availability <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> consumers. In May 2012<strong>the</strong> number of new ac<strong>to</strong>rs where approximately fifteen. The ma<strong>in</strong> entry has occurred <strong>in</strong>areas with a high population density, while <strong>the</strong>re has been no entry <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> country side.The <strong>to</strong>tal <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> number of pharmacies is 22 per cent. This <strong>in</strong>cludes foreign entrantssuch as Norwegian Apotek 1 and German DocMorris. 12The structural changes and <strong>the</strong> temporary alleviation of <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g law have resulted <strong>in</strong><strong>to</strong>ugher competition <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r where low <strong>productivity</strong> firms have left <strong>the</strong> marketand been replaced by firms with higher <strong>productivity</strong>. The number of firms that has left <strong>the</strong>market is higher than <strong>the</strong> number of new entrants. Therefore, fewer but larger s<strong>to</strong>res nowserve a larger proportion of <strong>the</strong> population <strong>in</strong> Sweden. 13 In l<strong>in</strong>e with <strong>the</strong> decreas<strong>in</strong>g numberof s<strong>to</strong>res <strong>the</strong> number of employees has <strong>in</strong>creased. However, <strong>the</strong> number of employeeshas not <strong>in</strong>creased at <strong>the</strong> same rate as <strong>the</strong> turnover <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry, which means that feweremployees serve a large number of cus<strong>to</strong>mers and <strong>the</strong> labour <strong>productivity</strong> has <strong>in</strong>creasedover time. 14There are significant differences <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> effects of <strong>the</strong> structural change of <strong>the</strong> market <strong>in</strong>different areas of Sweden. 15 In <strong>the</strong> period 1996-2009 <strong>the</strong> number of s<strong>to</strong>res decreased by16.2 per cent <strong>in</strong> city-areas with high population density while <strong>the</strong> number of s<strong>to</strong>res decreasedby 35.7 per cent <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> areas with low population density <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> country side. 16The sharp decrease <strong>in</strong> s<strong>to</strong>res <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> country side has resulted <strong>in</strong> a range of governmentalprograms focus<strong>in</strong>g on a diversified <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r even <strong>in</strong> areas with low population density.The programs have <strong>the</strong> objective <strong>to</strong> promote availability of public and commercial ser-11 Orth & Maican, 2012 p. 1112 Statskon<strong>to</strong>ret, 2012, pp. 39-4113 McK<strong>in</strong>sey, 2006 pp. 10714 McK<strong>in</strong>sey, 2006, pp. 113-11615 Tillväxtanalys, 2009, pp. 55-5616 Detailhandelsforum, 2012 pp. 131-13916


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rvices <strong>to</strong> all consumers. 17 Today <strong>the</strong>se objectives are <strong>to</strong> be achieved by <strong>the</strong> requirement thateach of Swedish regions (läns) have a “regional service program”. A central focus area is<strong>in</strong>creased local participation <strong>in</strong> public tender<strong>in</strong>g rounds and <strong>in</strong>itiatives <strong>to</strong> promote access<strong>to</strong> grocery shopp<strong>in</strong>g 18 .Ano<strong>the</strong>r program is <strong>the</strong> “local service solutions” 19 program, which focuses on coord<strong>in</strong>ationof public and commercial services by plac<strong>in</strong>g public service functions <strong>in</strong> for <strong>in</strong>stance <strong>retail</strong>outlets.Even though Sweden have not experienced large deregulations of <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> market dur<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> last twenty years, <strong>the</strong> large structural changes of <strong>the</strong> market has improved <strong>the</strong> <strong>productivity</strong><strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r. Still <strong>the</strong>re are several regulations <strong>in</strong> Sweden that restrict entry <strong>to</strong><strong>the</strong> market, cf. table 3.Table 3 Rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g barriers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Swedish <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rBarrierLabour legislation(LAS)Zon<strong>in</strong>g legislation(PBL)Note:TypeSubsec<strong>to</strong>rsaffectedEconomic type:rent (r )cost (c )discrim<strong>in</strong>a<strong>to</strong>ry (d)Scale All sec<strong>to</strong>rs cScale All sec<strong>to</strong>rs c,rEconomic effectDecrease flexibility and possibility<strong>to</strong> adjust <strong>the</strong> workforceafter season and demandMay prevent large s<strong>to</strong>re formats,and related efficiencyga<strong>in</strong>s for new or expand<strong>in</strong>gfirms. Time and cost consum<strong>in</strong>g<strong>to</strong> firmsSourceLagen om anställn<strong>in</strong>gsskyddPlan- och byglagOpen<strong>in</strong>g hours is unregulated <strong>in</strong> Sweden. The only regulated market regard<strong>in</strong>g product is <strong>the</strong> marke<strong>to</strong>f alcohol which is monopolised.Source: Institutet för tillväxtpolitiska studier, 2006, McK<strong>in</strong>sey, 200617 Reger<strong>in</strong>gens proposition, 2001/02:418 Regionala serviceprogra. ”Delredovisn<strong>in</strong>g” Februay 201019 ”Lokala servicelösn<strong>in</strong>ger”.17


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rChapter 4Economic potential of deregulationFrom 1995-2010 <strong>productivity</strong> grew by 3.5 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts less <strong>in</strong> Denmark than it did <strong>in</strong>Sweden on average and 1.5 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts less than <strong>the</strong> average of a peer group consist<strong>in</strong>gof Germany, <strong>the</strong> Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands and Sweden, cf. figure 3. This chapter estimates <strong>the</strong>potential of 1) catch<strong>in</strong>g up with peer group <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> rates and 2) reviv<strong>in</strong>g<strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> from remov<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> barriers identified <strong>in</strong> chapter 2.“Loss” of DKK 12.5bn from slow <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>retail</strong>If <strong>productivity</strong> performance had been at <strong>the</strong> same level as <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> peer group output <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>Danish <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r would have been 25 per cent above <strong>the</strong> level it is <strong>to</strong>day. This corresponds<strong>to</strong> approximately DKK12.5bn <strong>in</strong> 2010 (2005-prices), cf. box 3.Box 3 Estimat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> potential of achiev<strong>in</strong>g peer group <strong>productivity</strong><strong>growth</strong> ratesThe question answered is essentially what would gross value added <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Danish <strong>retail</strong>sec<strong>to</strong>r have been if gross value added per hour had grown at <strong>the</strong> same pace as <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> average of a peer group consist<strong>in</strong>g of Germany, <strong>the</strong> Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands and Sweden and<strong>to</strong>tal hours worked had developed as it actually have.Such an estimate is naturally a simplification and <strong>the</strong> estimate should be seen as an illustrationof <strong>the</strong> magnitude of <strong>the</strong> importance of <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r.4.2 The impact of zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> UKA recent study from <strong>the</strong> Spatial Economics Research Centre at <strong>the</strong> London School of Economicsestimate <strong>the</strong> effect of zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation on <strong>to</strong>tal fac<strong>to</strong>r <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>in</strong> super markets<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK. 20 They exam<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>troduction of more restrictive zon<strong>in</strong>gregulation on <strong>productivity</strong> based on s<strong>to</strong>re level data from a s<strong>in</strong>gle supermarket cha<strong>in</strong>. Thestudy uses <strong>the</strong> variation <strong>in</strong> restrictiveness <strong>in</strong> plann<strong>in</strong>g policy between local plann<strong>in</strong>g authoritiesacross <strong>the</strong> UK and f<strong>in</strong>d that <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>troduction of stricter zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation directlyreduces <strong>productivity</strong> both by reduc<strong>in</strong>g s<strong>to</strong>re size and by forc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>retail</strong> on<strong>to</strong> less productivesites. Us<strong>in</strong>g s<strong>to</strong>re level data from 2008 <strong>the</strong>y suggest that plann<strong>in</strong>g policies have imposed areduced of <strong>productivity</strong> by 20 per cent for new s<strong>to</strong>res opened <strong>in</strong> 2006.Their estimate have two components; <strong>the</strong> first component simulates what <strong>productivity</strong>would have been for a s<strong>to</strong>re opened <strong>in</strong> 2006 if <strong>productivity</strong> of new s<strong>to</strong>res had cont<strong>in</strong>ued <strong>to</strong>grow every open<strong>in</strong>g year, at <strong>the</strong> same rate after plann<strong>in</strong>g policies were <strong>in</strong>troduced as it did<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> period between 1966-86. 21 They <strong>the</strong>n compare <strong>the</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> level of this simulateds<strong>to</strong>re with <strong>the</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> level of a representative s<strong>to</strong>re as it was actually was <strong>in</strong> 2006and <strong>the</strong> authors attribute this difference <strong>in</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation. Theyf<strong>in</strong>d a difference <strong>in</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> of 16 per cent. The best fitt<strong>in</strong>g econometric model, con-20 Chesire, Hilber and Kaplanis, 201121 The <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> rate was 0.46 per cent per year <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> supermarket cha<strong>in</strong> used <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> English study.18


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rtroll<strong>in</strong>g for observable fac<strong>to</strong>rs, between s<strong>to</strong>re age and <strong>productivity</strong> used <strong>in</strong> this first componentis presented <strong>in</strong> Figure 10.The second component contributes with 4 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts and is an estimate of <strong>the</strong>impact of <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g land prices and reduced s<strong>to</strong>re size <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> more restrictive plann<strong>in</strong>gareas. Here <strong>the</strong> counterfactual is <strong>the</strong> average predicted <strong>productivity</strong> assum<strong>in</strong>g that alls<strong>to</strong>res faced <strong>the</strong> lowest regula<strong>to</strong>ry restrictiveness observed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> sample. They comparethis counterfactual with a representative s<strong>to</strong>re located <strong>in</strong> a plann<strong>in</strong>g area with averagerestrictiveness and f<strong>in</strong>d a difference <strong>in</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> of 4 per cent. Comb<strong>in</strong>ed this yields a<strong>to</strong>tal negative effect on <strong>productivity</strong> of <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation of 20 per cent on a s<strong>to</strong>reopened <strong>in</strong> 2006.Figure 10 Fitted relationship between <strong>productivity</strong> and year ofopen<strong>in</strong>gSource: Chesire, Hilber and Kaplanis (2011)Ano<strong>the</strong>r way <strong>to</strong> illustrate <strong>the</strong> effect of <strong>the</strong> plann<strong>in</strong>g policy is <strong>to</strong> exam<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong> relationshipbetween s<strong>to</strong>re size and <strong>productivity</strong>. The simple relationship between <strong>productivity</strong> ands<strong>to</strong>re size for <strong>the</strong> s<strong>to</strong>res used <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> English study is shown <strong>in</strong> Figure 11. The vertical l<strong>in</strong>esshow <strong>the</strong> size restrictions <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Danish zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation and <strong>the</strong> average s<strong>to</strong>re size <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>UK sample. The mean floor space of <strong>the</strong> s<strong>to</strong>res <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK sample is 46710 sq. feet or 4340m 2 . The maximum s<strong>to</strong>re size allowed by <strong>the</strong> Danish zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation is 3500 m 2 or approximately37500 sq. ft., which is lower than <strong>the</strong> mean s<strong>to</strong>re size <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK supermarketcha<strong>in</strong>. This suggests that <strong>the</strong> Danish zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation is stricter than <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK at least with respect <strong>to</strong> size of outlets.19


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rFigure 11 Relationship between <strong>productivity</strong> and s<strong>to</strong>re sizeDK size limit foro<strong>the</strong>r <strong>retail</strong>outletsDK size limit for grocery s<strong>to</strong>resAverage s<strong>to</strong>re size <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK samplesampleSource:Chesire, Hilber and Kaplanis (2011), PlanlovenIn <strong>the</strong> UK restrictions on out-of-<strong>to</strong>wn <strong>retail</strong>, developments started <strong>to</strong> emerge <strong>in</strong> 1988.“Town Centre First Policies”, as it is called, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir current form were <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong> 1996.The policy forces developers <strong>to</strong> demonstrate that <strong>the</strong> local area needs more shopp<strong>in</strong>gspace and fur<strong>the</strong>rmore <strong>to</strong> demonstrate that <strong>the</strong>re is no suitable site <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>wn centre.The suitability of sites is determ<strong>in</strong>ed by Local Development Plans. In this way <strong>the</strong> plann<strong>in</strong>gsystem is manag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> specific sites for development much as <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulationis <strong>in</strong> Denmark. Effectively <strong>the</strong> regulation prohibits out-of-<strong>to</strong>wn supers<strong>to</strong>res. 22In Denmark <strong>the</strong> specific provisions regard<strong>in</strong>g <strong>retail</strong> were enacted <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation<strong>in</strong> 1997, i.e. one year later than <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK. 23 This suggests that <strong>the</strong> accumulated effect of<strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation could be nearly <strong>the</strong> same <strong>in</strong> Denmark as <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK. We assess <strong>the</strong>economic effect of zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> estimates from <strong>the</strong> UK.4.3 Long term <strong>productivity</strong> ga<strong>in</strong> of 13 per cent <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> grocery<strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rWhen apply<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> estimate from <strong>the</strong> UK <strong>in</strong> calculat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> effect of zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation <strong>in</strong>Denmark several fac<strong>to</strong>rs are important <strong>to</strong> keep <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d.First, <strong>the</strong> estimated effect is accumulated over a 20-year period and <strong>the</strong> counterfactualsupermarket would <strong>the</strong>refore not be 20 per cent more productive than a supermarket22 LSE Centre Piece (2011) p. 27.23 Miljøm<strong>in</strong>isteriet (2002) p. 9.20


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>ropened before 2006 as <strong>the</strong> effect on <strong>the</strong> newest grocery outlets is larger than on outletsopened when <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g laws was first <strong>in</strong>troduced. This also implies that <strong>the</strong> effect of <strong>the</strong>zon<strong>in</strong>g law is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g over time accord<strong>in</strong>g <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK study. Hence <strong>the</strong> time horizon <strong>in</strong>which a 20 per cent <strong>productivity</strong> ga<strong>in</strong> could be achieved is uncerta<strong>in</strong>. Here we exam<strong>in</strong>ethree scenarios with different transition periods of 7 years, 15 years and 20 years respectively.The length of this transition period would depend on <strong>the</strong> rate at which <strong>the</strong> grocery<strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r adapts <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> new regula<strong>to</strong>ry environment, and be <strong>in</strong>fluenced by among o<strong>the</strong>rth<strong>in</strong>gs how and whe<strong>the</strong>r domestic and foreign <strong>retail</strong>ers choose <strong>to</strong> compete <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> hypermarketsegment.Second, it is not straightforward what share of <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r is affected. The UK studyestimates <strong>the</strong> effect on <strong>the</strong> average grocery outlet <strong>in</strong> a cha<strong>in</strong> of grocery s<strong>to</strong>res. Here weassume that <strong>the</strong> regulation affect <strong>the</strong> s<strong>to</strong>re formats supermarkets (35 per cent of revenue)and supers<strong>to</strong>res (23 per cent of revenue) 24 . Toge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>se s<strong>to</strong>re formats account for 58per cent of grocery <strong>retail</strong> revenue and thus we assume that <strong>the</strong> ga<strong>in</strong>s could be realised <strong>in</strong>58 per cent of <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r. 25The UK study <strong>in</strong>cluded two effects. One was an average effect on <strong>productivity</strong> and <strong>the</strong>o<strong>the</strong>r a location effect. 26 We assume that <strong>the</strong> location effect of 4 per cent also appears <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> discount segment which accounts for 29 per cent of grocery <strong>retail</strong> revenue <strong>in</strong> Denmark.Based on <strong>the</strong>se assumptions <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal long-term effect of remov<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> regulation wouldbe a <strong>productivity</strong> ga<strong>in</strong> of 13 per cent <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> grocery <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r. Depend<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong> speedat which this potential can be reaped this corresponds <strong>to</strong> between DKK 0.5bn and DKK1.6bn <strong>in</strong> 2020, cf. Table 4. For fur<strong>the</strong>r details on <strong>the</strong> calculation, please refer <strong>to</strong> Box 4.Table 4 Effect <strong>in</strong> 2020 under three scenariosScenario 1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3Productivity <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>in</strong>2020, 100=base scenario113 106 104DKK billion (2005-prices) 1.6 0.8 0.5Note:Source:Scenario1: 7-year transition period, Scenario2: 15 year transition period, Scenario3: 20 year transitionperiod. The effect is calculated us<strong>in</strong>g number of hours worked <strong>in</strong> 2010 and <strong>the</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>in</strong>dexfor 2020 calculated under <strong>the</strong> three scenarios.Statistics Denmark, Chesire, Hilber and Kaplanis (2011), McK<strong>in</strong>sey (2010), Copenhagen Economics24 Supermarkets operate between 400 and2500 sq.m and supers<strong>to</strong>res operate between 2500 and 5000 sq.m. McK<strong>in</strong>sey (2010)p. 12425 These s<strong>to</strong>re formats account for a much larger share of sales.26 This effect was <strong>the</strong> difference between <strong>the</strong> least restrictive areas and <strong>the</strong> average restricted area.21


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rBox 4 Calculat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> potentialThe estimate of <strong>the</strong> effect of zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK had two components. First anaverage effect of 16 per cent (we call this <strong>the</strong> size effect) and second a location effec<strong>to</strong>f 4 per cent between <strong>the</strong> average and <strong>the</strong> least restrictive plann<strong>in</strong>g area (we call this<strong>the</strong> location effect).Source:We calculate <strong>the</strong> potential <strong>in</strong> 2020 <strong>in</strong> three steps: First we determ<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong> share of <strong>the</strong> grocery <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r which is affected bychang<strong>in</strong>g zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation. We suggest that <strong>the</strong> supermarket and supers<strong>to</strong>re segments,constitut<strong>in</strong>g 58 per cent of <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r, are affected by both <strong>the</strong> size effectand <strong>the</strong> location effect of <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, we assess that <strong>the</strong>discount segment, 29 per cent of <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r, is affected by <strong>the</strong> location effect, butnot by <strong>the</strong> size effect as discounters usually operate at s<strong>to</strong>re sizes below <strong>the</strong> limit<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation (part of <strong>the</strong> discount segment could be affected if consumerssubstituted away from <strong>the</strong> discount segment <strong>to</strong> larger and cheaper supermarkets/supers<strong>to</strong>res).We assume that nei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> hypermarket segment (7 per cent)nor <strong>the</strong> convenience segment (5 per cent) is affected by <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation. Second we calculate a <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>in</strong>dex for <strong>the</strong> grocery <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r without zon<strong>in</strong>gregulation. Each of <strong>the</strong> grocery <strong>retail</strong> segments is assumed <strong>to</strong> have <strong>in</strong>dex 100<strong>in</strong>itially. For each sub segment we calculate an <strong>in</strong>dex without zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation assum<strong>in</strong>gthat <strong>the</strong> effects are as determ<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> step 1. Based on segment shares wecalculate <strong>the</strong> impact on <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal grocery <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r. The is calculated for threedifferent transition periods for effects <strong>to</strong> be achieved. We call <strong>the</strong>se scenario1, scenario2,and scenario3. In scenario1 <strong>the</strong>re is full effect <strong>in</strong> 2020, <strong>in</strong> scenario2 half of<strong>the</strong> impact is achieved <strong>in</strong> 2020 and <strong>in</strong> scenario 3 one third of <strong>the</strong> effect is achieved<strong>in</strong> 2020. The long term effect, equivalent <strong>to</strong> scenario1, is estimated <strong>to</strong> be 13 percent or <strong>in</strong>dex 113. Third we estimate <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>in</strong> DKK by calculat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> difference between GVAcorrespond<strong>in</strong>g <strong>to</strong> each of <strong>the</strong> three scenarios and a basel<strong>in</strong>e with <strong>in</strong>dex 100 for2010 grocery <strong>retail</strong> <strong>productivity</strong>. We use <strong>the</strong> number of hours worked <strong>in</strong> grocery <strong>retail</strong><strong>in</strong> 2010.We arrive at a long term impact <strong>in</strong> scenario1 of DKK 1.6billion.Eurostat, McK<strong>in</strong>sey (2010), Copenhagen Economics.If <strong>productivity</strong> ga<strong>in</strong>s of this magnitude were not only achieved <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> grocery subsec<strong>to</strong>r,but also <strong>in</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r subsec<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>the</strong> potential effect of deregulation would be higher. It is likelythat changes <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation would reach beyond <strong>the</strong> grocery subsec<strong>to</strong>r. Thecurrent zon<strong>in</strong>g law <strong>in</strong> Denmark is also limit<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> entrance of out-of-<strong>to</strong>wn shopp<strong>in</strong>g centresand non-grocery <strong>retail</strong>ers of for <strong>in</strong>stance furniture and electronic equipment. Henceour estimate is conservative and underestimates <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong> change.The estimates are naturally subject <strong>to</strong> uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty. First, we assume that <strong>the</strong> effects ofzon<strong>in</strong>g regulation are <strong>the</strong> same <strong>in</strong> Denmark and <strong>the</strong> UK. This might not be <strong>the</strong> case, ands<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> UK zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation appears <strong>to</strong> be less strict than <strong>the</strong> Danish, this might contribute<strong>to</strong> an underestimation of <strong>the</strong> impacts. Second, <strong>the</strong> time horizon dur<strong>in</strong>g which <strong>the</strong><strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r can adapt <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> less strict zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation is uncerta<strong>in</strong>, and changes mayoccur more rapidly than <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> above scenarios. 27 Third, <strong>the</strong> estimate is static <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> sensethat it does not consider what will happen <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> use of <strong>in</strong>put fac<strong>to</strong>rs such as labour if27 The replacement of exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>retail</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ck and entry of new firms is considered a ma<strong>in</strong> driver of US <strong>retail</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong>dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> 1990s; see Haltiwanger et al (2005).22


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rzon<strong>in</strong>g regulation was removed. This would likely be lower as <strong>retail</strong>ers will substituteaway from this <strong>in</strong>put fac<strong>to</strong>r.This be<strong>in</strong>g said <strong>the</strong>re are reasons why <strong>the</strong> potential could be even bigger. First, when calculat<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> counterfactual <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK study, <strong>productivity</strong> is assumed <strong>to</strong> grow at a ratesimilar <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> rate before zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation was <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK. The <strong>productivity</strong>performance of <strong>the</strong> U.S. grocery <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r suggests that <strong>productivity</strong> could <strong>in</strong> fact havegrown even faster. From 1990 <strong>to</strong> 2000, <strong>to</strong>tal fac<strong>to</strong>r <strong>productivity</strong> (TFP) grew by 3 per centper year on average <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> U.S. <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r. 28 Second, <strong>the</strong> estimate applies <strong>the</strong> averagelevel of regula<strong>to</strong>ry restrictiveness of all s<strong>to</strong>res <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> sample. In Denmark <strong>the</strong> size-cap isset by central government and may <strong>the</strong>refore reflect a stricter regula<strong>to</strong>ry environmentthan <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> average <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK as suggested <strong>in</strong> Figure 11.Rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g regula<strong>to</strong>ry barriers cannot alone expla<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> gapIn chapter 2 we identified a range of barriers that may impede <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong><strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r, cf. table 1. Of <strong>the</strong>se, zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation seems <strong>to</strong> be <strong>the</strong> most significant barrier.Still <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal gap <strong>in</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> between Denmark and peer countries cannotbe accounted for by <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation alone. Nei<strong>the</strong>r can <strong>the</strong> removal of all identifiedbarriers be expected <strong>to</strong> deliver peer country <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> rates. First <strong>the</strong> list ofregula<strong>to</strong>ry barriers is not exhaustive and secondly o<strong>the</strong>r barriers such as general bus<strong>in</strong>essregulation and framework conditions play an important role as well. These <strong>in</strong>clude, butare not limited <strong>to</strong>, country specific barriers such as country size, language barriers, wagelevels, taxation, environmental regulation etc.Political objectives must be taken <strong>in</strong><strong>to</strong> accountOne of <strong>the</strong> objectives of <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation is <strong>to</strong> limit <strong>the</strong> travel distance <strong>to</strong> <strong>retail</strong> s<strong>to</strong>res.Relax<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation and adoption larger s<strong>to</strong>re formats could imply longer distances<strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> nearest outlet. A recent estimate is that <strong>the</strong> establishment of 10-25 hypermarkets<strong>to</strong>ge<strong>the</strong>r with 80 new supers<strong>to</strong>res will result <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> clos<strong>in</strong>g of 300 <strong>to</strong> 800 smalleroutlets. 29Opponents of a deregulation of <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g law argue that a deregulation may lead <strong>to</strong> adverseeffects <strong>in</strong> terms of abandoned mid<strong>to</strong>wns, negative environmental impact, and a riskof market concentration. 30 A forum of <strong>in</strong>terest organisations from <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r, consumerorganisations (Detailhandelsforum) has delivered a report <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> M<strong>in</strong>ister forGrowth and raised <strong>the</strong> concern that competition may <strong>in</strong> fact decl<strong>in</strong>e follow<strong>in</strong>g a deregulationand entrance of hypermarkets as <strong>the</strong> large Danish grocery conglomerates may be <strong>the</strong>only ac<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> hypermarket segment. Detailhandelsforum suggests that <strong>in</strong>creasedcompetition would require that foreign cha<strong>in</strong>s enter Denmark and that due <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> limitedmarket potential large <strong>in</strong>ternational cha<strong>in</strong>s may not be will<strong>in</strong>g <strong>to</strong> pursue <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestmentand hence that <strong>the</strong>re are no guarantees that foreign cha<strong>in</strong>s would enter <strong>the</strong> market if <strong>the</strong>zon<strong>in</strong>g law was deregulated 31 .28 Blanchard (2003) p. 929 McK<strong>in</strong>sey (2010)30 Detailshandelsforum (2012) p. 18631 Detailhandelsforum (2012) p. 18323


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rWhe<strong>the</strong>r this concern is valid is not straightforward. For <strong>in</strong>stance Slovakia which hasapproximately <strong>the</strong> same population as Denmark is home <strong>to</strong> both Carrefour and Tescohypermarkets. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore foreign <strong>retail</strong>ers who operate with discount s<strong>to</strong>re formatssuch as Lidl and Aldi (German) are present <strong>in</strong> Denmark, cf. table 4. In addition <strong>the</strong> DanishCompetition and Consumer Authority has recently argued that <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g regulationpractically provides Bilka with a position as <strong>the</strong> only company operat<strong>in</strong>g with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> hypermarketsegment s<strong>in</strong>ce Bilka currently operates 15 s<strong>to</strong>res between 6,500 m 2 and15,000m 2 and entry is restricted <strong>in</strong><strong>to</strong> this segment. 32Table 5 European presence of <strong>in</strong>ternational grocery <strong>retail</strong>ersLarge scale formatsDiscount/small scaleformatsCarrefour Tesco Lidl AldiGermany x xFrance x x x xUK x x xItaly x xSpa<strong>in</strong> x x xPoland x x x xGreece x xHungary x X xBelgium x X xPortugal x X xCzech Republic x XSwedenDenmark X xSlovakia x x XXSource:CE analysis based on company websites.4.4 ConclusionThere is a significant economic potential <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> benefit of Danish consumers from clos<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> gap between Denmark and peer countries <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r. If <strong>the</strong> Danish<strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r had experienced <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> rates similar <strong>to</strong> those <strong>in</strong> peer countriess<strong>in</strong>ce 1995 valued added <strong>in</strong> <strong>retail</strong> would have been DKK 12.5bn higher than it was <strong>in</strong>2010.Achiev<strong>in</strong>g peer country <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> rates is not straight forward, but <strong>the</strong> Danishzon<strong>in</strong>g regulation seem <strong>to</strong> be a ma<strong>in</strong> barrier <strong>to</strong> achieve this goal due <strong>to</strong> its effects on entryand realiz<strong>in</strong>g economies of scale <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r.One <strong>in</strong>strument <strong>in</strong> clos<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> gap could be <strong>to</strong> decentralize <strong>the</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g lawsand give more authority <strong>in</strong> decisions on location and size of new s<strong>to</strong>res <strong>to</strong> local govern-32 The Danish Competition and Consumer Authority (2011) p. 5824


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rments. Whe<strong>the</strong>r this will <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>productivity</strong> is naturally uncerta<strong>in</strong> as it depends on <strong>the</strong>decisions of local authorities. It may though contribute <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> ga<strong>in</strong>s of <strong>the</strong> typesseen <strong>in</strong> Sweden s<strong>in</strong>ce 1995, as identified <strong>in</strong> section 2.3, i.e. <strong>the</strong> adoption of more productives<strong>to</strong>re formats, <strong>in</strong>creased deployment of new technologies, <strong>in</strong>troduce more competitionboth locally and from <strong>in</strong>ternational markets and contribute <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> development ofmore efficient supply cha<strong>in</strong>s.We estimate that remov<strong>in</strong>g zon<strong>in</strong>g regulation could contribute between DKK0.5bn andDKK 1.6bn <strong>in</strong> 2020 <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> grocery <strong>retail</strong> subsec<strong>to</strong>r alone.25


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rReferencesChesire, Paul, Hilber, Christian and Kaplanis, Ioannis(2011). “Evaluat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Effects of Plann<strong>in</strong>gPolicies on <strong>the</strong> Retail Sec<strong>to</strong>r: Or do Town CentreFirst Policies Deliver <strong>the</strong> Goods?”, Spatial EconomicsResearch Center Discussion Paper 66,London School of Economics.Danmarks Apotekerforen<strong>in</strong>g (2001, 2002, 2012)Årsberetn<strong>in</strong>g.Danish Competition and consumer authority (2011)Detailhandelsforum 2012, (2012) Detailhandlen iDanmark – gode rammer for <strong>in</strong>dkøb <strong>in</strong>denfor rimeligafstand, Detailhandelsforum til erhvervsogvækstm<strong>in</strong>isteren den 1. marts 2012Griffith, R. and Harmgart, H. (2008). “Supermarketsand Plann<strong>in</strong>g Regulation” CEPR Discussion Paper6713.Haltiwanger, J, Foster, L and Krizan, C.J (2005).“Market Selection, reallocation and Restructur<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> U.S. Retail Trade sec<strong>to</strong>r <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1990s. 2005Institut för tillväxtpolitiska studier (2006) – Detaljhandelnoch produktivitetstillväxten - Produktivitetsutveckl<strong>in</strong>gen<strong>in</strong>om svensk detaljhandel 1993-2004McK<strong>in</strong>sey (2010), ”Creat<strong>in</strong>g Economic Growth <strong>in</strong>Denmark Through Competition”. McK<strong>in</strong>sey CopenhagenNovember 2010.McK<strong>in</strong>sey (2006) – Sweden’s economic performance:Recent development, Current PrioritiesNordic competition authorities (2005) – NordicFood Market, a taste for competitionOrth Matilda and Maican, Florida (2012). “ Markandstrukturoch dynamik i dagligvaruhandeln” –Ekonomisk debatt nr 1 2012 årgång 4026


<strong>Barriers</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>growth</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>retail</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>rOrth, Matilda and Maican, Florida (2012). “A DynamicAnalysis of regulation and <strong>productivity</strong> <strong>in</strong><strong>retail</strong> trade”. IFN work<strong>in</strong>g paper no. 939, 2012.Reger<strong>in</strong>gens proposition (2001/02:4) – En politikför tillväxt och livskraft i hela landetStatskon<strong>to</strong>ret (2012) – En omreglerad apoteksmarknaddel 2, 2012:19Tillväxtanalys, (2009) – Befolkn<strong>in</strong>g, service och företagandei Sveriges gles- och landsbygderMIljøm<strong>in</strong>isteriet (2002), Planloven i Praksis.Rets<strong>in</strong>formation.dk: Planloven, Apotekerloven, Lægemiddelloven27

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!