11.07.2015 Views

Does History Matter – and how? Path Dependence in Housing

Does History Matter – and how? Path Dependence in Housing

Does History Matter – and how? Path Dependence in Housing

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Does</strong> <strong>History</strong> <strong>Matter</strong> – <strong>and</strong> <strong>how</strong>? <strong>Path</strong> <strong>Dependence</strong> <strong>in</strong> Hous<strong>in</strong>gBo BengtssonUPPSALA UNIVERSITYInstitute for Hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Urban ResearchP O Box 785SE–801 29 GÄVLE, Swedenphone +46 26 420 65 21email: bo.bengtsson@ibf.uu.sePaper presented at the Centre for Hous<strong>in</strong>g Policy, University of York, 14 March 2007[Please do not distribute or quote without the author’s permission!]


1<strong>Does</strong> <strong>History</strong> <strong>Matter</strong> – <strong>and</strong> <strong>how</strong>? <strong>Path</strong> <strong>Dependence</strong> <strong>in</strong> Hous<strong>in</strong>gBo BengtssonAbstract<strong>Path</strong> dependence <strong>in</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g is discussed from three different angles. The first part of thepaper is a critical analysis of James Mahoney’s strong def<strong>in</strong>ition of path dependence ascont<strong>in</strong>gent events at one po<strong>in</strong>t sett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to motion determ<strong>in</strong>istic <strong>in</strong>stitutional change. It isargued that a weaker <strong>and</strong> more relative def<strong>in</strong>ition of path dependence is more compatiblewith a contextualised actor-based analysis, which is often the heart of political <strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>stitutional history. Such a weak concept also makes possible a dist<strong>in</strong>ction betweendecision-mak<strong>in</strong>g, agenda-sett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> perceptual path dependence <strong>and</strong> allows for explanations<strong>in</strong> terms of comb<strong>in</strong>ations of the different mechanisms efficiency, legitimacy <strong>and</strong> power.The second part is a general discussion of path dependence (weakly def<strong>in</strong>ed) as a tool forhistorical analysis of hous<strong>in</strong>g regimes <strong>and</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g policy. The policy theory of the stateprovid<strong>in</strong>g correctives to the hous<strong>in</strong>g market makes tenures <strong>and</strong> other market regulationsimportant <strong>in</strong>stitutional elements, which, together with the longevity <strong>and</strong> physical sluggishnessof hous<strong>in</strong>g, may imply rather strong path dependence. This is corroborated by theparadoxical <strong>and</strong> persistent differences between the hous<strong>in</strong>g regimes of the five Nordiccountries.The third part of the paper briefly presents the establish<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutionalisation of theunique Swedish corporatist rental policy. The historical review is focused on the four phases(‘establish<strong>in</strong>g’,’ construction’,’ saturation’ <strong>and</strong> ‘retrenchment’) of a ‘development curve ofhous<strong>in</strong>g provision’, which is claimed to be of general relevance. In the analysis of the Swedishcase a number of the elements associated with path dependence are identified.IntroductionFollow<strong>in</strong>g the sem<strong>in</strong>al works by Douglass North <strong>and</strong> Robert Putnam (North 1990; Putnam1993; Pierson 2003) the concept of path dependence has been given grow<strong>in</strong>g attention <strong>in</strong>historically oriented social studies. E.g. path dependence is often seen as the basic causalmechanism <strong>in</strong> historical versions of <strong>in</strong>stitutional theory (Peters 1999: 62–63). The generalidea beh<strong>in</strong>d the concept is that if the historical development takes one direction at one po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong>time, certa<strong>in</strong>, otherwise feasible, alternative paths will be closed – or at least difficult to reach– at a later po<strong>in</strong>t. This can be analysed either as self-re<strong>in</strong>forc<strong>in</strong>g or reactive sequences(Mahoney 2000: 508–9). In a political perspective the idea of path dependence highlights atleast two well known general phenomena: <strong>how</strong> structural, cultural <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional constra<strong>in</strong>tsfrom the past may limit the possibility of change, <strong>and</strong> <strong>how</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional <strong>in</strong>ertia may limit thewill<strong>in</strong>gness to change.In the paper I take my po<strong>in</strong>t of departure from one theoretical perspective on pathdependence, presented by James Mahoney, <strong>and</strong> suggest <strong>how</strong> his model should be developedto better deal with the role of history <strong>in</strong> decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g by actors with <strong>in</strong>tentions. Then I goon to discuss more precisely <strong>how</strong> such a perspective may be applied to hous<strong>in</strong>g policy <strong>and</strong>hous<strong>in</strong>g regimes, illustrat<strong>in</strong>g my discussion with empirical f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs from a comparative studyof hous<strong>in</strong>g policy <strong>in</strong> the five Nordic countries Denmark, Sweden, Norway, Icel<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong>F<strong>in</strong>l<strong>and</strong>. F<strong>in</strong>ally I discuss <strong>how</strong> the historical development of one particular idiosyncratic case,


2the unique Swedish form of hous<strong>in</strong>g corporatism, can be understood <strong>in</strong> terms of pathdependence. 1<strong>Path</strong> dependence <strong>and</strong> social action – a critical comment on James MahoneyIn an often quoted article ’<strong>Path</strong> dependence <strong>in</strong> historical sociology’, James Mahoney criticisesvague def<strong>in</strong>itions of path dependence that say little more than ’history matters’ or ’the past<strong>in</strong>fluences the future’. To def<strong>in</strong>e the concept only as forms of ’path analysis’ does notdemonstrate why path-dependent patterns <strong>and</strong> sequences merit special attention, he claims.Instead Mahoney (1) def<strong>in</strong>es path dependence specifically as ’historical sequences <strong>in</strong> whichcont<strong>in</strong>gent events set <strong>in</strong>to motion <strong>in</strong>stitutional patterns or event cha<strong>in</strong>s that have determ<strong>in</strong>isticproperties’ (my italics). This implies (2) that the identification of path dependence <strong>in</strong>volvesboth trac<strong>in</strong>g a given outcome back to a particular set of historical events, <strong>and</strong> s<strong>how</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>how</strong>these events are themselves cont<strong>in</strong>gent <strong>and</strong> cannot be expla<strong>in</strong>ed on the basis of prior historicalconditions. In consequence, (3) s<strong>in</strong>ce cont<strong>in</strong>gency cannot be established without theory, thespecification of path dependence is always a theory-laden process, mean<strong>in</strong>g that ’deviant casestudies’, which analyse cases where an outcome predicted by theory did not occur, offer one<strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g form of analysis of path dependence (Mahoney 2000: 507–8). I will call thesepropositions ‘Mahoney’s three theses on path dependence’.Even though I agree with Mahoney’s second <strong>and</strong> third theses, about the necessity to trace pathdependence by writ<strong>in</strong>g history backwards <strong>and</strong> the necessity of path-dependence analysis to betheory-laden (<strong>and</strong> certa<strong>in</strong>ly about the value of deviant case studies), I question the merits ofhis ‘strong’ def<strong>in</strong>ition of path dependence. If the concept is reserved for situations where onecont<strong>in</strong>gent event determ<strong>in</strong>istically leads to other events or to certa<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional outcomes,there would not be many cases left to analyse <strong>in</strong> the social sciences where determ<strong>in</strong>isticcausation can seldom be claimed. Instead I suggest a weak def<strong>in</strong>ition, where one event that ismore or less cont<strong>in</strong>gent considerably changes the probability of other subsequent events or<strong>in</strong>stitutional outcomes. This weak concept of path dependence would transform Mahoney´sdemarcation between cont<strong>in</strong>gency <strong>and</strong> determ<strong>in</strong>acy <strong>in</strong>to a matter of degrees on a scale go<strong>in</strong>gfrom cont<strong>in</strong>gency to determ<strong>in</strong>acy, where prior events are considerably more cont<strong>in</strong>gent thansubsequent. This weak def<strong>in</strong>ition would, of course, make path dependence more difficult todist<strong>in</strong>guish from other types of correlations, but also more useful <strong>in</strong> the analysis of real-lifesocial processes.Admittedly my weak def<strong>in</strong>ition aga<strong>in</strong> blurs the dist<strong>in</strong>ction between path dependence <strong>and</strong> pathanalysis that Mahoney worries about. <strong>Does</strong> that mean that we are back to ‘history matters’?The answer is yes, but <strong>in</strong> my op<strong>in</strong>ion path dependence is better def<strong>in</strong>ed – <strong>and</strong> dist<strong>in</strong>guishedfrom other forms of path analysis – <strong>in</strong> relation to Mahoney’s second <strong>and</strong> third theses, as ahistorical pattern where a certa<strong>in</strong> outcome can be traced back to a particular set of events onthe basis of empirical observation guided by some social theory. <strong>Path</strong> dependence would thenbe a particular form of path analysis that focuses historical events <strong>and</strong> specifies <strong>in</strong> theoreticalterms the elements that build up the path. It assumes that history matters – but the empirical1 The paper is based on a book on Swedish that presents the results from the Nordic comparative study(Bengtsson et al 2006). I thank my Nordic friends <strong>and</strong> co-writers Erl<strong>in</strong>g Annaniassen, Lotte Jensen, HannuRuonavaara <strong>and</strong> Jón Rúnar Sve<strong>in</strong>sson for fruitful co-operation, which has also left its traces <strong>in</strong> this paper.However, I take full responsibility for all its shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs, <strong>in</strong> particular for any rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g misunderst<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>gs ofhous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>in</strong> Norway, Denmark, F<strong>in</strong>l<strong>and</strong> or Icel<strong>and</strong>.


3challenge is not to ‘prove’ that general assumption, but to identify <strong>in</strong> what respect <strong>and</strong> viawhat type of mechanism history matters <strong>in</strong> a certa<strong>in</strong> context.The ma<strong>in</strong> problem with Mahoney’s strong def<strong>in</strong>ition, as I see it, is that it does not seem veryfruitful – or even applicable – <strong>in</strong> a context of actor-based analysis, which is often the heart ofpolitical <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional history. The dichotomy between cont<strong>in</strong>gency <strong>and</strong> determ<strong>in</strong>acy isdifficult to apply to actors with <strong>in</strong>tentions, who can be assumed to follow some logic ofmean<strong>in</strong>gful action – which may be more or less rational. Without go<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to the complexitiesof different theories of action, I would say that most students would agree that the behaviourof political actors is to some extent explicable <strong>in</strong> terms of bounded rational action, thoughseldom <strong>in</strong> the formal terms of determ<strong>in</strong>istic, probabilistic or cont<strong>in</strong>gent. 2In an actor-based analysis the typical case of (weak) path dependence is where actors more orless deliberately design <strong>in</strong>stitutions at po<strong>in</strong>t (or po<strong>in</strong>ts) A, <strong>in</strong>stitutions which at a later po<strong>in</strong>t Bsets the rules of the political game between the same or other actors. In retrospect, thehistorical development can be perceived as an ongo<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> self-re<strong>in</strong>forc<strong>in</strong>g cha<strong>in</strong> of gamesbetween actors, <strong>in</strong>stitutional change, new games, new <strong>in</strong>stitutions, etc. One strength of theweak def<strong>in</strong>ition is, paradoxically, that it makes it possible to identify degrees or modes of pathdependence. In a perspective of contextualised rational action one might, <strong>in</strong>spired by StevenLukes (1974), differentiate between three different ‘faces’ or forms of path dependence.Earlier more ’cont<strong>in</strong>gent’ events at po<strong>in</strong>t A may at po<strong>in</strong>t B have an effect on (I)decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g (where actors choose other alternatives due to what happened at po<strong>in</strong>t A),(II) agenda-sett<strong>in</strong>g (where other alternatives come up on the political agenda due to whathappened at po<strong>in</strong>t A) or (III) perceptions (where other alternatives are conceivable to actorsdue to what happened at po<strong>in</strong>t A).Inspired by R<strong>and</strong>all Coll<strong>in</strong>s, Mahoney presents an <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g typology of path-dependentexplanations of <strong>in</strong>stitutional reproduction, where he makes a dist<strong>in</strong>ction between utilitarian,functional, power <strong>and</strong> legitimation explanations. The mechanism of reproduction <strong>in</strong> utilitarianexplanation is the rational cost-benefit assessment of the <strong>in</strong>stitution by actors, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>functional explanation the function of the <strong>in</strong>stitution for an overall system. In legitimationexplanation the mechanism at work is the belief of actors <strong>in</strong> the morality or appropriateness ofthe <strong>in</strong>stitution, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> power explanation the mechanism is support by an elite group of actors.Depend<strong>in</strong>g on the mechanism, the effect at po<strong>in</strong>t B of the cont<strong>in</strong>gent event that occurred atpo<strong>in</strong>t A would be that otherwise more efficient, more functional or more legitimate<strong>in</strong>stitutions would not be available or, <strong>in</strong> the power variation, that an elite group is empoweredthat otherwise would not have been so (Mahoney 2000: 517–24).Mahoney’s typology mixes rational choice, functionalism, idealism <strong>and</strong> power analysis. In myop<strong>in</strong>ion, what he presents as alternative explanations actually implies a choice betweentheoretical perspectives, <strong>and</strong> it is difficult to conceive of an analytical framework that wouldbe neutral between his four explanations as alternatives <strong>in</strong> an empirical analysis. 3 There are2 Cf. Somerville <strong>and</strong> Bengtsson 2002 <strong>and</strong> Bengtsson <strong>and</strong> Somerville 2002 for a discussion on social analysisbased on a perspective of contextualised rational action.3 This problem seems to be a consequence of Mahoney’s strong def<strong>in</strong>ition of path dependence as completecont<strong>in</strong>gency at po<strong>in</strong>t A <strong>and</strong> complete determ<strong>in</strong>acy at po<strong>in</strong>t B, which makes it difficult to <strong>in</strong>clude comb<strong>in</strong>ations ofdifferent mechanisms <strong>in</strong> the model. The weak def<strong>in</strong>ition also makes it possible to account for <strong>in</strong>stitutionalchange without necessarily play<strong>in</strong>g the ‘external shock’ card. In a perspective of path dependence observed<strong>in</strong>stitutional always dem<strong>and</strong>s an explanation, but with a weak def<strong>in</strong>ition change may e.g. be caused by <strong>in</strong>ternalcontradiction <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>stitutions themselves (<strong>and</strong> thus path dependent <strong>in</strong> itself). ‘But different <strong>in</strong>stitutions rest on


4also other types of explanations that may be relevant besides the four <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> Mahoney’smodel. 4In an actor-based analysis the po<strong>in</strong>t of departure should <strong>in</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciple be subjective <strong>and</strong> basedon (1) <strong>how</strong> the actors conceive of the situation at po<strong>in</strong>t B, (2) what alternatives enter <strong>in</strong>toactors’ ’calculi’ (which may be more or less explicit or sophisticated), <strong>and</strong> (3) <strong>how</strong> actors<strong>in</strong>teract with other actors <strong>in</strong> the decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g process (which may <strong>in</strong> fact be anondecision-mak<strong>in</strong>g process). This means that Mahoney’s utilitarian mechanism is the coreof the analysis, even though it may be def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> less perfectly rationalistic end economicterms than Mahoney seems to imply.In a perspective of contextualised rational action legitimacy <strong>and</strong> power, like economicefficiency, are seen <strong>in</strong> the light of actors’ preferences. In this perspective it seems morefruitful to dist<strong>in</strong>guish between mechanisms of efficiency, legitimacy <strong>and</strong> power. Theefficiency mechanism of path dependence has to do with the coord<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g capacity ofestablished <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>and</strong> with the transactions costs of chang<strong>in</strong>g them (cf. North 1990; Hall<strong>and</strong> Taylor 1996: 945; Pierson 2000). The legitimacy mechanism may enter as an <strong>in</strong>put <strong>in</strong>actors’ calculi either directly, via their own preferences, or <strong>in</strong>directly, via their perceptions ofwhat is seen as legitimate <strong>in</strong> the society at large. This type of mechanism has to do with thenormative logic beh<strong>in</strong>d established <strong>in</strong>stitutions, not least among actors who have been<strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> design<strong>in</strong>g them (cf. March <strong>and</strong> Olsen 1989: 41). Correspond<strong>in</strong>gly the powermechanism may enter <strong>in</strong>to actors’ preferences both directly <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>directly. Directly <strong>in</strong>decid<strong>in</strong>g which actors are allowed to take part <strong>in</strong> the decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> with what power.Indirectly via perceptions of power relations <strong>in</strong> the larger society. Institutional arrangementsare never neutral <strong>in</strong> terms of power, which also affects the conditions of chang<strong>in</strong>g them(Thelen 1999: 394–96). 5This discussion also has implications for the role of theory <strong>in</strong> the analysis of path dependence.In Mahoney’s model theory is needed to decide what events at po<strong>in</strong>t A are cont<strong>in</strong>gent or not.In an analysis of path dependence <strong>in</strong> a perspective of contextualised rational action the role oftheory is first to make sense of actors <strong>and</strong> decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>and</strong> second to help expla<strong>in</strong> moreprecisely the mechanisms def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the path, i.e. what aspects of the event A, <strong>and</strong> its effects,def<strong>in</strong>e the rules of the game <strong>and</strong> actors’ preference orders at po<strong>in</strong>t B. Unlike Mahoney’sstrong version of path dependence, where a move from the cont<strong>in</strong>gent to the determ<strong>in</strong>isticcalls for an explanation <strong>in</strong> terms of one <strong>in</strong>clusive mechanism, the weak <strong>and</strong> actor-orientedversion allows for comb<strong>in</strong>ations of different mechanisms, as long as they can all be <strong>in</strong>cluded<strong>in</strong> the reconstruction of actors’ preferences <strong>and</strong> perception of the rules of the game at po<strong>in</strong>t B.<strong>Path</strong> dependence <strong>and</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g regimesThe discussion above on Mahoney’s concept of path dependence concluded <strong>in</strong> a modificationof his def<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>and</strong> model, better adapted to actor-based historical analysis of <strong>in</strong>stitutions.<strong>Path</strong> dependence was seen as a situation where the decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g situation at po<strong>in</strong>t B <strong>in</strong>different foundations, <strong>and</strong> so the processes that are likely to disrupt them will also be different, thoughpredictable’ (Thelen 1999: 297).4 One often discussed factor – that may actually have determ<strong>in</strong>istic consequences at po<strong>in</strong>t B – is physical ortechnical change at po<strong>in</strong>t A (cf. Hughes 1983). This ’technical explanation’ may be of particular relevance tohous<strong>in</strong>g policy; e.g. if hous<strong>in</strong>g estates at po<strong>in</strong>t A are produced as large-scale units, this would certa<strong>in</strong>ly putdef<strong>in</strong>ite restra<strong>in</strong>ts on decisions about hous<strong>in</strong>g provision at po<strong>in</strong>t B.5 Maloney’s functional mechanism seems to be less relevant <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>tentional perspective (see Elster 1989: 99–100 for a general criticism of functional explanations <strong>in</strong> social science).


5terms of either perceptions <strong>and</strong> preferences of actors or the conditions of <strong>in</strong>teraction isaffected by previous events at po<strong>in</strong>t or po<strong>in</strong>ts A. The effects may be on the explicit choicebetween alternatives, on what alternatives enter the agenda or on what alternatives areperceived by actors. The mechanism may be changes <strong>in</strong> efficiency, legitimacy or power or acomb<strong>in</strong>ation of these.How can a perspective of actor-oriented path dependence be applied to the field of hous<strong>in</strong>g? 6Are there any specific characteristics that have to be considered <strong>in</strong> the historical analysis ofthis sector of society?Hous<strong>in</strong>g policy <strong>in</strong> the Western countries is best perceived as the state provid<strong>in</strong>g correctives tothe hous<strong>in</strong>g market. This means that market contracts serve as the ma<strong>in</strong> mechanism fordistribut<strong>in</strong>g hous<strong>in</strong>g, while state <strong>in</strong>tervention has the form of correctives, def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g theeconomic <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional sett<strong>in</strong>g of those market contracts (cf. Bengtsson 2001; Oxley <strong>and</strong>Smith 1996: 2–3, make a similar observation). In pr<strong>in</strong>ciple hous<strong>in</strong>g is distributed by means ofvoluntary contracts between buyer <strong>and</strong> seller, between l<strong>and</strong>lord <strong>and</strong> tenant, <strong>and</strong> so forth.Hous<strong>in</strong>g is perceived as an <strong>in</strong>dividual good, which, as far as possible, should be distributed <strong>in</strong>accordance with <strong>in</strong>dividual consumer preferences.The normative basis of this mode of provision is that hous<strong>in</strong>g is seen not only as an importantelement of citizens’ welfare, but also – <strong>and</strong> perhaps above all – as a market good. Hence, <strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong> contrast to other welfare commodities, politically def<strong>in</strong>ed needs of hous<strong>in</strong>g are not fulfilledby direct state allocation but by state correctives to the market. This particular ‘policy theory’makes the markets for hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> house build<strong>in</strong>g the most important arenas where hous<strong>in</strong>g isdistributed <strong>and</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g provision is decided. 7This policy theory of state correctives to the market can be contrasted to other welfare sectors.Ulf Torgersen has po<strong>in</strong>ted out the specificity of hous<strong>in</strong>g policy by describ<strong>in</strong>g it as ‘the wobblypillar under the welfare state’. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to him, <strong>in</strong> the typical welfare sector fairly clearst<strong>and</strong>ards have been extracted from the vague concept of need, st<strong>and</strong>ards that def<strong>in</strong>e when<strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>in</strong> charge are responsible to take action, <strong>and</strong> lack of conformity to those st<strong>and</strong>ardsis subject to legal action from the prospective recipient. Those elements are seldom discerned<strong>in</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g provision, what is strik<strong>in</strong>g is rather the contrast <strong>in</strong> those respects between hous<strong>in</strong>g<strong>and</strong> other welfare sectors (Torgersen 1987: 116–18).This specific policy theory of hous<strong>in</strong>g also has implications for what should be <strong>in</strong> focus <strong>in</strong> theanalysis of path dependence <strong>in</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g. In a policy field based on market distribution thema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutions are those that def<strong>in</strong>e the rules of the game <strong>in</strong> the market. In hous<strong>in</strong>g thecrucial <strong>in</strong>stitutions are tenure forms <strong>and</strong> other types of market regulations, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gnon-profit organizations act<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the market. 8A well known characteristic factor of hous<strong>in</strong>g provision is related to the longevity <strong>and</strong>physical sluggishness of the hous<strong>in</strong>g stock per se, often discussed by economists as6 In Bengtsson et al 2006, this model of weak actor-based path dependence has been applied to the developmentof hous<strong>in</strong>g policy <strong>in</strong> the five Nordic countries.7 A policy theory can be def<strong>in</strong>ed as ‘... the total of causal <strong>and</strong> other assumptions underly<strong>in</strong>g a policy’(Hoogerwerf 1990: 285–86).8 See Ruonavaara 1992 for a discussion on types <strong>and</strong> forms of tenure. ‘Hous<strong>in</strong>g tenures are <strong>in</strong>stitutions, sets ofpractices that regulate a particular field of human action <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>teraction’ (Ruonavaara 2005: 214). The market assuch – <strong>and</strong> the hous<strong>in</strong>g market more specifically – should also be seen as an <strong>in</strong>stitution <strong>in</strong> this mean<strong>in</strong>g.


6‘peculiarities of hous<strong>in</strong>g markets’ (Stahl 1985; Arnott 1987). S<strong>in</strong>ce hous<strong>in</strong>g estates have anaverage lifetime of some 50 years, only a marg<strong>in</strong>al percentage of the stock is replaced by newproduction <strong>in</strong> a certa<strong>in</strong> year. Because of this, political measures aimed at hous<strong>in</strong>g productionnormally have their full impact only <strong>in</strong> the very long run. This would be a strong example ofthe efficacy mechanism of path dependence. 9As market regulations hous<strong>in</strong>g tenures def<strong>in</strong>e the rights of exchange <strong>and</strong> possession that arefundamental to a capitalist economy, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> Western societies any change <strong>in</strong> such rules maybe regarded as a threat both to exist<strong>in</strong>g property owners <strong>and</strong> more generally to an economybased on <strong>in</strong>dividual security of property. Even if there are no formal constra<strong>in</strong>ts aga<strong>in</strong>stchang<strong>in</strong>g such rules virtually over night, considerable political restra<strong>in</strong>t may be expected, e.g.avoid<strong>in</strong>g to force through major changes with the support of only a narrow parliamentarymajority. This would be an example of the legitimacy mechanism of path dependence. 10Together these two factors – the sluggishness of the hous<strong>in</strong>g stock <strong>and</strong> the normativepresumption aga<strong>in</strong>st changes <strong>in</strong> property rights – may mean that the conditions of pathdependence, <strong>and</strong> historical <strong>in</strong>stitutionalisation <strong>in</strong> general, are of a different character <strong>in</strong>hous<strong>in</strong>g than <strong>in</strong> other policy fields. If we comb<strong>in</strong>e them with the general mechanisms ofefficiency, legitimacy <strong>and</strong> power we would <strong>in</strong>deed expect a higher degree of path dependencethan <strong>in</strong> many other policy fields.Why so different? The Nordic hous<strong>in</strong>g regimesThe importance of tenure forms was the po<strong>in</strong>t of departure of a research project, where thefive hous<strong>in</strong>g systems of Denmark, Sweden, Norway, F<strong>in</strong>l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Icel<strong>and</strong> were compared <strong>in</strong> ahistorical perspective of path dependence. The differences between the national systems ofhous<strong>in</strong>g provision <strong>in</strong> the Nordic countries are remarkable. It is true that modern hous<strong>in</strong>gpolicy <strong>in</strong> all the five countries has been ‘social’ <strong>in</strong> the mean<strong>in</strong>g that an important goal hasbeen to provide decent hous<strong>in</strong>g to households of lesser means. However, the <strong>in</strong>stitutionalarrangements chosen to achieve this goal differ fundamentally. As a matter of fact theorganizational forms aimed at implement<strong>in</strong>g the national policies are so dissimilar that itseems well justified to describe the five countries as represent<strong>in</strong>g five different hous<strong>in</strong>gregimes. 11In Denmark hous<strong>in</strong>g policy has been primarily directed towards rental hous<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong> particular<strong>in</strong> estates owned <strong>and</strong> managed by public hous<strong>in</strong>g associations, organized <strong>in</strong> smallself-governed units where local tenants have a high degree of self-management or ‘hous<strong>in</strong>gdemocracy’. In Sweden hous<strong>in</strong>g policy has also been implemented primarily by means ofrental hous<strong>in</strong>g owned <strong>and</strong> managed by public hous<strong>in</strong>g companies, though, <strong>in</strong> contrast to theirDanish counterparts, these companies are controlled by the local municipalities. Sweden alsohas the largest share of co-operative hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Europe.9 This form sluggishness is of course physical <strong>and</strong> technical rather than <strong>in</strong>stitutional, but it has <strong>in</strong>stitutionalimplications as well as can be seen <strong>in</strong> the next footnote.10 One aspect of this mechanism is that the longevity of hous<strong>in</strong>g estates provides unique prerequisites oflong-term f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g, which, <strong>in</strong> turn, gives banks <strong>and</strong> other f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions a strong <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> fixed <strong>and</strong>predictable rules.11 Here def<strong>in</strong>ed broadly as the set of fundamental pr<strong>in</strong>ciples accord<strong>in</strong>g to which a national system of hous<strong>in</strong>gprovision is organized.


7In Norway hous<strong>in</strong>g policy has been ma<strong>in</strong>ly based on <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>and</strong> co-operative ownership,<strong>and</strong> the social rental sector represents only a marg<strong>in</strong>al percentage of the total stock. In Icel<strong>and</strong>too, owner-occupation has been used as a hous<strong>in</strong>g policy <strong>in</strong>strument, though <strong>in</strong> this case<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g strong elements of <strong>in</strong>dividual self-build. In F<strong>in</strong>l<strong>and</strong>, f<strong>in</strong>ally, hous<strong>in</strong>g policy has notbeen directed at any particular forms of tenure or ownership.The <strong>in</strong>stitutional arrangements of hous<strong>in</strong>g provision <strong>in</strong> the Nordic countries have a number of<strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g dist<strong>in</strong>ctive features when compared to other countries as well. In Denmark,Norway <strong>and</strong> Sweden, though not <strong>in</strong> F<strong>in</strong>l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Icel<strong>and</strong>, strong popular movementorganizations have played a lead<strong>in</strong>g role <strong>in</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g provision. Norway <strong>and</strong> Sweden haveco-operative hous<strong>in</strong>g movements without comparison elsewhere, <strong>and</strong> Sweden also has aworld unique tenant’s movement with an almost corporatist <strong>in</strong>fluence on the rental policy (seebelow). In Denmark the national tenant’s movement is much weaker than its Swedishcounterpart, but <strong>in</strong>stead the democratic forms of local self-government <strong>in</strong> the public rentalsector are unparalleled <strong>in</strong> Europe.Swedish, Danish <strong>and</strong> Norwegian hous<strong>in</strong>g policies have been described as ‘universal’ <strong>and</strong>directed towards all types of households <strong>and</strong> most segments of the hous<strong>in</strong>g market. F<strong>in</strong>nish<strong>and</strong> Icel<strong>and</strong>ic hous<strong>in</strong>g policies on the other h<strong>and</strong> have been described as ‘selective’ <strong>and</strong>oriented more directly towards households of lesser means <strong>and</strong> based to a large extent on<strong>in</strong>dividual means-test<strong>in</strong>g. 12The large differences between hous<strong>in</strong>g regimes <strong>in</strong> five countries that share a number ofsimilarities <strong>in</strong> other respects is a puzzle <strong>and</strong> can <strong>in</strong> itself be seen as an <strong>in</strong>dication of pathdependence. Without some form of structural restra<strong>in</strong>ts or <strong>in</strong>stitutional <strong>in</strong>ertia we wouldexpect some signs of convergence, <strong>in</strong> particular consider<strong>in</strong>g the regular collaboration <strong>and</strong>exchange of ideas that goes on between Nordic politicians, officials <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>terestorganisations. 13 But the Nordic countries have reta<strong>in</strong>ed their divergent hous<strong>in</strong>g regimes for atleast 60 years by now.Trac<strong>in</strong>g path dependence <strong>in</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>gHow can the concept of path dependence be applied to the development of hous<strong>in</strong>g regimes?As already <strong>in</strong>dicated, three central elements of a path-dependence analysis are (1) the event orevents at po<strong>in</strong>t or po<strong>in</strong>ts A, where the historical path is ‘chosen’; (2) the decision-mak<strong>in</strong>gprocess at po<strong>in</strong>t B, where the effects of the choice at po<strong>in</strong>t A become visible; <strong>and</strong> (3) themechanism or mechanisms that expla<strong>in</strong> the effects of the event at po<strong>in</strong>t A on thedecision-mak<strong>in</strong>g situation at po<strong>in</strong>t B.The logical way to identify these elements if we want to analyse the development of hous<strong>in</strong>gregimes <strong>and</strong> tenure policy would be to start at po<strong>in</strong>t B, which would typically be an importantpolitical decision on tenure-related issues. Decisions on tenure legislation, organisation <strong>and</strong>ownership, or on subsidies directed towards specific tenures, are obvious c<strong>and</strong>idates. Here wewould expect path dependence to be visible <strong>in</strong> the contents of the decision, <strong>in</strong> the politicaldebate <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> the general discourse. If we f<strong>in</strong>d that some, otherwise plausible, paths are seenas closed by the <strong>in</strong>volved actors, this would be an <strong>in</strong>dication of <strong>how</strong> to f<strong>in</strong>d po<strong>in</strong>t A, by go<strong>in</strong>g12 After the changes <strong>in</strong> selective direction that have recently taken place <strong>in</strong> the three Sc<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>avian countries, <strong>and</strong>rather dramatically <strong>in</strong> Norway, this dist<strong>in</strong>ction is less clear-cut than it used to be (see Bengtsson 2001 for adiscussion on the mean<strong>in</strong>g of the dichotomy universal-selective <strong>in</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g policy.13 Kemeny <strong>and</strong> Lowe 1999 discuss convergence <strong>and</strong> divergence <strong>in</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g.


8backwards <strong>in</strong> history to a situation where closure took place. Whereas po<strong>in</strong>t B would typicallyhave the outward appearance of a central <strong>and</strong> important political decision, the event at po<strong>in</strong>t Amay not have been much debated or even observed at the time, e.g. presented as a provisionalsolution to a specific <strong>and</strong> acute problem. By scrut<strong>in</strong>iz<strong>in</strong>g the situation both at po<strong>in</strong>t A <strong>and</strong>po<strong>in</strong>t B it should <strong>in</strong> most cases also be possible to say someth<strong>in</strong>g about what type ofmechanism or mechanisms that were at work between the two events.The methodological conclusion is that to f<strong>in</strong>d po<strong>in</strong>t A one should start at po<strong>in</strong>t B, which istypically a more visible political event. If we want more theoretical names than A <strong>and</strong> B Isuggest we call po<strong>in</strong>t A critical juncture <strong>and</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t B political focal po<strong>in</strong>t. 14 It should also beunderl<strong>in</strong>ed that a political focal po<strong>in</strong>t may sometimes also be a critical juncture – <strong>in</strong> relation tosome future po<strong>in</strong>t B. Such a ‘focal critical juncture’ has sometimes been called a formativemoment – <strong>in</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g policy they may <strong>in</strong> reality often rather be more drawn-out ‘formativeperiods’ – where actors <strong>in</strong>tentionally <strong>in</strong>duce historical change <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutions (cf. Rothste<strong>in</strong>1998).There is, <strong>how</strong>ever, one <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g complication <strong>in</strong> this approach. If there is <strong>in</strong>deed pathdependence, the alternatives that were closed at the critical juncture A may not even be visiblewhen we <strong>in</strong>vestigate the political focal po<strong>in</strong>t B. In Lukes’ terms, it may not be a case of‘decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g’ path dependence, but of the ’agenda-sett<strong>in</strong>g’ or even ’perceptual’ versions(cf. above), <strong>and</strong> then we may not f<strong>in</strong>d any trace of the deserted path when study<strong>in</strong>g thedecision process. It is true that alternatives seen as unrealistic by actors may sometimes stillbe commented on, but if that is not the case such forms of path dependence must be spottedby some form of counterfactual analysis (cf. below).The development curve of hous<strong>in</strong>g provisionWhat decisions about hous<strong>in</strong>g policy would be the best c<strong>and</strong>idates for serv<strong>in</strong>g as politicalfocal po<strong>in</strong>ts? First, <strong>in</strong> consequence with what has already been said, such decisions should beabout tenures, but over time there have typically been many of those <strong>in</strong> a national hous<strong>in</strong>ghistory. In the Nordic project the po<strong>in</strong>t of departure was taken <strong>in</strong> theoretically def<strong>in</strong>edhistorical phases, correspond<strong>in</strong>g to the general challenges that most Western hous<strong>in</strong>g systemshave gone through. The idea is that when a system is challenged structurally or discursivelyone would expect some sort of crisis <strong>and</strong> discussion of change. This should also be the po<strong>in</strong>twhere <strong>in</strong>stitutional constra<strong>in</strong>ts gets visible <strong>in</strong> political debate <strong>and</strong> decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g..In general terms we can identify four rather dist<strong>in</strong>ctive phases <strong>in</strong> the hous<strong>in</strong>g history of theNordic countries <strong>in</strong> the 20-th century. First, an establishment phase from early urbanizationup to the second world war, a period when hous<strong>in</strong>g provision went from be<strong>in</strong>g a field ofrecurrent crisis management on an ad hoc basis to be<strong>in</strong>g a permanent item on the politicalagenda. Second, an expansive construction phase (<strong>in</strong> both physical <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional terms)triggered by the post-war hous<strong>in</strong>g shortage <strong>and</strong> grow<strong>in</strong>g political ambitions <strong>in</strong> terms ofhous<strong>in</strong>g st<strong>and</strong>ards. In the Nordic countries this phase cont<strong>in</strong>ues up to the seventies, whenhous<strong>in</strong>g dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> quantitative terms was more or less saturated. Third, we can identify amanagement phase (or saturation phase) when production of new hous<strong>in</strong>g was successivelyreplaced by renewal <strong>and</strong> management of the exist<strong>in</strong>g stock. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>and</strong> still go<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>in</strong> theNordic countries, we have a privatisation phase or, <strong>in</strong> more general terms, retrenchmentphase, start<strong>in</strong>g between 1990 <strong>and</strong> 2000, when some of the state <strong>in</strong>stitutions of hous<strong>in</strong>g14 Cf. respectively Collier <strong>and</strong> Collier 1991 <strong>and</strong> Schell<strong>in</strong>g 1980, who, <strong>how</strong>ever, uses the term ‘focal po<strong>in</strong>t’ with asomewhat different mean<strong>in</strong>g.


9provision were abolished or reorganized. 15 Correspond<strong>in</strong>g ‘structural development curves’ ofhous<strong>in</strong>g provision can probably be drawn up for most other Western countries as well, so thephase model could be a valuable tool <strong>in</strong> comparative hous<strong>in</strong>g research.As already <strong>in</strong>dicated, counterfactual analysis is often important part of a perspective of pathdependence. What alternative development would have been possible at po<strong>in</strong>t B, if the eventat po<strong>in</strong>t A would not have occurred? The <strong>in</strong>dividual l<strong>in</strong>ks <strong>in</strong> a certa<strong>in</strong> historical cha<strong>in</strong> mayoften be analysed counterfactually by mak<strong>in</strong>g use of records of the political discourse <strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>teraction. It is more difficult to make a counterfactual analysis of the overall <strong>in</strong>stitutionaldevelopment, i.e. the result of the whole cha<strong>in</strong> of decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutionalisation.<strong>Path</strong> dependence <strong>in</strong> the Nordic hous<strong>in</strong>g regimesIn the Nordic project the counterfactual analysis of one country was carried out with thedevelopment <strong>in</strong> the other countries as contrast<strong>in</strong>g relief. When <strong>and</strong> why were alternativestrategies ‘discarded’, that might have lead to a development closer to the hous<strong>in</strong>g regimes ofthe other countries? Did these alternatives at some po<strong>in</strong>t of time enter the political agenda? Orwere the political, <strong>in</strong>stitutional <strong>and</strong> structural conditions never such that those alternativeswere seen as realistic or even perceived of?The ma<strong>in</strong> result of the Nordic study is that the differences between the five hous<strong>in</strong>g regimeshave been remarkably persistent all through the various challenges of the four historicalphases. The <strong>in</strong>stitutional changes that have taken place <strong>in</strong> each country have been <strong>in</strong>cremental<strong>in</strong> the sense that the new arrangements have consistently reta<strong>in</strong>ed dist<strong>in</strong>ct features of thepreced<strong>in</strong>g ones. This is true even <strong>in</strong> the cases where reforms have actually been launched as‘system shifts’ by political actors (Bengtsson et al 2006: chap. 7). 16What is the solution to the puzzle of “why so different”? Very briefly, <strong>in</strong> the formative periodof the hous<strong>in</strong>g regimes, between the turn of the century 1900 <strong>and</strong> World War II, different –<strong>and</strong> more or less ‘cont<strong>in</strong>gent’ – solutions were chosen to deal with the hous<strong>in</strong>g problems ofurbanisation <strong>in</strong> each country. When more comprehensive programmes of hous<strong>in</strong>g policy were<strong>in</strong>troduced after the war it was seen as efficient to make use of the already exist<strong>in</strong>g, if stillundeveloped, organisations <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutions to implement the new programmes. Dur<strong>in</strong>g theconstruction phase, with its massive production of new hous<strong>in</strong>g, the five hous<strong>in</strong>g regimeswere successively consolidated <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutionalised. From that time we can repeatedlyobserve <strong>how</strong> the mechanisms of efficiency, legitimacy <strong>and</strong> power counteract <strong>in</strong>stitutionalchange (Bengtsson et al 2006: chap. 9).The counterfactual analysis gives further evidence of the strength of path dependence <strong>in</strong>Nordic hous<strong>in</strong>g policy. Not s<strong>in</strong>ce 1946, at the time of the post-war hous<strong>in</strong>g reforms, havethere been serious political discussions or a plausible possibility <strong>in</strong> any of the five countries of‘import<strong>in</strong>g’ a hous<strong>in</strong>g regime similar to any of the other four. By that time, more precisely,the non-socialist parties <strong>in</strong> Denmark advocated a ‘F<strong>in</strong>nish’ system of selective support to both15 The phase model is <strong>in</strong>spired by a similar model <strong>in</strong> Jensen 1995: 229–30.16 It is true that remarkable <strong>in</strong>stitutional change can be observed <strong>in</strong> the Norwegian hous<strong>in</strong>g regime, where theuniversal regime s<strong>in</strong>ce the 1970s has been successively transformed to what <strong>in</strong> practice is a selective system.This transformation did, <strong>how</strong>ever, largely take place ‘beh<strong>in</strong>d politicians’ back’, when the price control onco-operative dwell<strong>in</strong>gs was successively abolished due to strong market pressure from owner-occupation <strong>and</strong>unregulated co-operative dwell<strong>in</strong>gs. S<strong>in</strong>ce the development was a consequence of <strong>in</strong>herent contradictions <strong>in</strong> theNorwegian hous<strong>in</strong>g regime, it may actually be seen as an example of path-dependent change (Bengtsson et al2006: chap. 4; cf. Thelen 1999: 394–96).


10rental hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> owner-occupation, while on Icel<strong>and</strong>, <strong>in</strong> contrast, the parties to the leftwanted to complement the support of owner-occupation by build<strong>in</strong>g social rental hous<strong>in</strong>g,which would also lead to a F<strong>in</strong>nish solution. In Sweden at the same time there was discussionswith<strong>in</strong> the govern<strong>in</strong>g Social Democratic party between advocates of a ‘Norwegian’ system ofsocially oriented co-operative hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> supporters of the system based on rentals ownedby municipal companies that was actually chosen. After that the other Nordic regimes havestill been used as contrast<strong>in</strong>g examples <strong>in</strong> national hous<strong>in</strong>g debates, but the <strong>in</strong>stitutions of thenational regimes have grown so strong that no serious import attempts have been made(Bengtsson et al 2006: 350–55). 17Swedish hous<strong>in</strong>g corporatism – a case of path dependence?The Swedish rental market is completely dom<strong>in</strong>ated by collective negotiations on rents <strong>and</strong>other hous<strong>in</strong>g conditions between l<strong>and</strong>lords <strong>and</strong> tenant’s unions. In this section I will discussthis absolutely unique form of hous<strong>in</strong>g corporatism <strong>in</strong> a perspective of path dependence. Thiscan be seen as a deviant case study of the type that Mahoney recommends to students of pathdependence. It is a deviant case not only empirically but also theoretically, s<strong>in</strong>ce there areauthors who see corporatism as <strong>in</strong>compatible with consumer organisations <strong>and</strong> ‘policy takers’(Offe 1985: 239–42, Williamson 1989: 169–70; cf. Bengtsson 1995: 235–38). I will arguethat the development of the ‘deviant’ Swedish system can be well understood with<strong>in</strong> aframework of path dependence. 18An important <strong>in</strong>gredient <strong>in</strong> the corporatist system is the extremely strong <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutionalisedSwedish tenants’ movement. Almost half of all Swedish rental households are members ofsome tenants’ union, which is a far higher percentage than <strong>in</strong> any other country. The tenants’movement is strongly <strong>in</strong>tegrated under the auspices of the National Union of Tenants. 19 The<strong>in</strong>stitutional basis is the corporatist system of collective rent negotiations <strong>and</strong> the so-calleduse-value system of rent-sett<strong>in</strong>g l<strong>in</strong>ked to the negotiations. Virtually all rents <strong>in</strong> Sweden areset with<strong>in</strong> this system, which is rather complicated <strong>in</strong> its details. 20Another ma<strong>in</strong>stay of the Swedish hous<strong>in</strong>g regime are the non-profit municipal hous<strong>in</strong>gcompanies, which make up the public rental sector <strong>in</strong> Sweden; there is normally one company<strong>in</strong> each municipality. 21 The rent negotiations <strong>in</strong> the public sector are based on the total cost ofthe company, <strong>and</strong> the arguments typically focus both on what costs are reasonable <strong>and</strong> on <strong>how</strong>those costs should be distributed between different districts, estates <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual dwell<strong>in</strong>gs.In pr<strong>in</strong>ciple this distribution should reflect consumer preferences <strong>and</strong> not relative costs(Turner 1988: 260–61).17 Cf. Lipset <strong>and</strong> Rokkan’s well-known thesis that the modern party systems have reflected political cleavages atthe time of transition to democracy <strong>in</strong> different countries – for decades after those cleavages have lost theirpolitical importance Lipset <strong>and</strong> Rokkan 1967: 30, 50–55).18 The corporatist system of rent-sett<strong>in</strong>g is one of four <strong>in</strong>stitutional pillars under the Swedish hous<strong>in</strong>g regime, theother three be<strong>in</strong>g the universal policy theory, the unitary social rental market <strong>and</strong> the municipal hous<strong>in</strong>gcompanies. Together these four <strong>in</strong>terrelated pillars can be said to def<strong>in</strong>e the Swedish hous<strong>in</strong>g regime (Bengtssonet al 2006: chap. 3).19 Other tenants’ associations exist, <strong>and</strong> occasionally they also have a collective rent-sett<strong>in</strong>g agreement with al<strong>and</strong>lord, but the national organisation with its subunits is the completely dom<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g representative of Swedishtenants.20 See Bengtsson 1994 for a more complete presentation of the system <strong>and</strong> its logic.21 See Bengtsson 1991 for a presentation of Swedish municipal hous<strong>in</strong>g companies; the important th<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> thepresent context is that no means-test<strong>in</strong>g or needs-test<strong>in</strong>g is required to get a municipal rental dwell<strong>in</strong>g.


11In the private rental sector, which is about the same size as the public sector, collective rentnegotiations are not based on the l<strong>and</strong>lords’ total costs, but on comparison with the rents ofsimilar dwell<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> the public sector. The l<strong>in</strong>k between the two sectors is the right touse-value trials based on the use-value paragraph of the Rental Act. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to thisparagraph, a claimed rent – public or private – can be rejected as unreasonable if it is found tobe considerably higher than the rents charged for dwell<strong>in</strong>gs with the same use-value <strong>in</strong> thesame local market. Use-value comparisons are made primarily with the rents of public rentaldwell<strong>in</strong>gs as bench-mark, which gives the non-profit municipal hous<strong>in</strong>g companies the role asprice-leaders <strong>in</strong> the local rental markets. If a private l<strong>and</strong>lord dem<strong>and</strong>s a considerably higherrent than the rent-level <strong>in</strong> the public sector, the tenant can take the case to the rent tribunal.This makes the Swedish rental sector an unusually clear-cut case of a ‘unitary social rentalmarket’ (cf. Kemeny 1995: 4).What makes the Swedish rental system corporatist even <strong>in</strong> formal terms is first that the rightto collective negotiations of tenants’ associations is legally regulated <strong>in</strong> the Rent NegotiationAct of 1978. Furthermore, the regional rent tribunals that serve as court of first <strong>in</strong>stance <strong>in</strong>use-value trials, consists of one representative of the l<strong>and</strong>lords’ organisation (either private orpublic) <strong>and</strong> one representative of the tenants’ union, together with a neutral chairperson, wellversed <strong>in</strong> the law. The National Union of Tenants also plays an important part as politicallobbyist <strong>and</strong> creator of public op<strong>in</strong>ion on hous<strong>in</strong>g issues, with strong l<strong>in</strong>ks to the SocialDemocratic party. The organisation is also a regular participant, together with the l<strong>and</strong>lords’organisations, <strong>in</strong> government commissions on rental policy.Different explanations to Sweden’s unique corporatist rental policy have been suggested,some of them quite plausible at first sight, but none really conv<strong>in</strong>c<strong>in</strong>g. The Social Democraticdom<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong> Swedish political life, <strong>and</strong> the high Swedish membership rates <strong>in</strong> voluntaryorganisations are two explanations that have sometimes been proposed, but <strong>in</strong> both respectsthe Sc<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>avian neighbours Denmark <strong>and</strong> Norway have similar records – but no comparabletenants’ movement. It has also been claimed, <strong>in</strong> a public choice perspective, that a large rentalsector make tenants an important group to appeal to for vote-maximiz<strong>in</strong>g politicians(Meyerson, Ståhl <strong>and</strong> Wickman 1990: 92–120). The problem with that hypothesis is that othercountries, most prom<strong>in</strong>ently Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> Germany, have larger rentalsectors but weaker tenants’ movement. 22 As we have seen the use-value system is part of auniversal hous<strong>in</strong>g policy <strong>and</strong> an <strong>in</strong>tegrated social rental market, but such <strong>in</strong>stitutions can befound <strong>in</strong> other European countries, with weakly organised tenants, so that is not the fullanswer either.Of course, we cannot completely rule out explanations <strong>in</strong> terms of the size <strong>and</strong> structure of therental sector, party politics, ideology or traditions of collective action, they may even benecessary conditions. But, s<strong>in</strong>ce the hous<strong>in</strong>g regimes of other countries have similar features,while the Swedish tenants’ organisation <strong>and</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g corporatism are unique, such general <strong>and</strong>external explanations are obviously not sufficient. So it seems well justified to look for a morecontextual <strong>and</strong> cont<strong>in</strong>gent explanation <strong>in</strong> terms of path dependence. This is what I will try todo <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g brief history of the Swedish rental policy, which is organised accord<strong>in</strong>g tothe four phases of the ‘development curve of hous<strong>in</strong>g provision’ presented above. 2322 In absolute membership the German tenants’ movement is even somewhat larger than the Swedish, butexpressed as a percentage its coverage is much smaller.23 Space allows only an extremely short version of the story; a somewhat longer short story, with references –<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> Swedish – is told <strong>in</strong> Bengtsson et al 2006: chap. 3.


12The establishment phaseThe period of the First World War witnessed the first permanent organisation of Swedishtenants. Economic crisis had led to a general breakdown of housebuild<strong>in</strong>g, with serioushous<strong>in</strong>g shortage, <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g rents <strong>and</strong> outright poverty. In a law from 1916 the municipalitieswere granted the right to set up special units for mediation <strong>in</strong> rental conflicts betweenl<strong>and</strong>lords <strong>and</strong> tenants. Those ‘rent tribunals’ had one member well versed <strong>in</strong> the law, one‘well versed <strong>in</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g production’ <strong>and</strong> one ‘with knowledge about the hous<strong>in</strong>g conditions ofpeople of small means’. Though tenants’ associations were barely existent at the time, thisoptional <strong>in</strong>stitution was the start of corporatist representation. Next year a provisional RentControl Act was passed as a restriction to the l<strong>and</strong>lords’ possibilities to take advantage of theirmarket power <strong>in</strong> a situation of hous<strong>in</strong>g shortage. As long as the crisis prevailed all rent<strong>in</strong>creases should be approved by the rent tribunals. A few years after the war, <strong>in</strong> 1923, theprovisional law was abolished <strong>and</strong> the rental market was aga<strong>in</strong> deregulated. This was onetrigger<strong>in</strong>g factor beh<strong>in</strong>d the foundation of the National Union of Tenants the same year.In the <strong>in</strong>terwar period the rules of the games on the rental market were def<strong>in</strong>ed by the oldRental Act of 1907 with its rather week security of tenure. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the economic crisis of thethirties, the situation was sharpened, <strong>and</strong> a series of rental strikes <strong>and</strong> boycotts took place, <strong>in</strong>particular <strong>in</strong> Gothenburg. A government commission, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g representatives of theorganisations on both sides, was <strong>in</strong>itiated <strong>in</strong> order to settle the disturbances <strong>and</strong> normalize therelations. The result was a new Rental Act, still not grant<strong>in</strong>g security of tenure, which was asetback by the tenants’ movement. On the other h<strong>and</strong> the decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g process was seenas a political recognition of the organisation, <strong>and</strong> one seat on the new mediation boards forrental conflicts was reserved for a local representative of the tenants.The new Rental Act had not even come <strong>in</strong>to force when war broke out, <strong>and</strong> though Swedenaga<strong>in</strong> succeeded to stay out, build<strong>in</strong>g production went down <strong>and</strong> rents went up. In 1942 aprovisional rent control was <strong>in</strong>troduced, this time comb<strong>in</strong>ed with direct security of tenure. Arent tribunal <strong>in</strong> each municipality was responsible of the implementation, aga<strong>in</strong> with a neutralchairperson <strong>and</strong> one representative of each party on the hous<strong>in</strong>g market. A national RentCouncil was also appo<strong>in</strong>ted to function as board of appeal <strong>and</strong> with the further task to decideon the annual adjustments of rent levels. In practice the Rent Council had a strongdiscretionary <strong>in</strong>fluence on the development of the rental market dur<strong>in</strong>g the war – <strong>and</strong> forconsiderable time thereafter.The Rent Control Act <strong>and</strong> its implementation meant a def<strong>in</strong>ite political acceptance of thetenants’ movement. One precondition was that already <strong>in</strong> the thirties the National Union ofTenants had said no to wildcat strikes <strong>and</strong> other militant measures of rental conflict. Now theadm<strong>in</strong>istrative co-responsibility of the implementation of the rental policy at all levelsguaranteed the organisation strong <strong>in</strong>fluence.The decision of 1942 was politically uncontroversial <strong>and</strong> regarded as a practical <strong>and</strong>provisional response to the crisis. At the time no one foresaw its formative importance. Thetemporary legislation was actually to survive until 1978.The construction phaseIn the years follow<strong>in</strong>g the war a number of important decisions on hous<strong>in</strong>g were taken by theSwedish parliament. The foundation was laid to the universal hous<strong>in</strong>g policy that has


13prevailed s<strong>in</strong>ce. The municipal hous<strong>in</strong>g companies were seen as the ma<strong>in</strong> cornerstone of thispolicy, <strong>and</strong> they were now given the ‘universal’ task to provide hous<strong>in</strong>g to all types ofhouseholds regardless of <strong>in</strong>come. 24The hous<strong>in</strong>g shortage did not go down after the war, <strong>and</strong> there was considerable politicalconsensus that the Rent Control Act could not be abolished immediately. Instead it wasprolonged year after year, always with the explicit reservation that it was only provisional <strong>and</strong>should be discont<strong>in</strong>ued once the market had reached balance. In the fast-grow<strong>in</strong>g public rentalsector, rents were set <strong>in</strong> cost-based collective negotiations from 1958, but <strong>in</strong> the private sectorone problem rema<strong>in</strong>ed to be solved: Tenants’ right to security of tenure had by now developed<strong>in</strong>to a generally accepted social norm, which was seen as impossible to uphold effectively onan unregulated market.A solution to this deadlock was not worked out until 1968 when a new permanent Rental Actwas f<strong>in</strong>ally passed. The compromise was that tenants were assured security of tenure, whilethe rent control was replaced by the use-value system of rent-sett<strong>in</strong>g described above. Thechairman of the National Union of Tenants was <strong>in</strong> fact the <strong>in</strong>ventor of this rather orig<strong>in</strong>alsystem – first <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong> a provisional law from 1956 – <strong>and</strong> when the idea was accepted byhis opposite party, the National Federation of Private Property Owners, the political partieshad no other option than to follow suit. 25The new <strong>and</strong> more liberal use-value system of rent-sett<strong>in</strong>g was accepted by the parliament <strong>in</strong>1968. However, s<strong>in</strong>ce the hous<strong>in</strong>g shortage was worse than ever <strong>in</strong> some places, time was notconsidered ripe to implement it <strong>in</strong> the whole rental market. It was first <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong> new-builtestates <strong>and</strong> last <strong>in</strong> the privately owned hous<strong>in</strong>g stock <strong>in</strong> the large cities. Needless to say theorganised <strong>in</strong>terests <strong>in</strong> the rental market had a major role <strong>in</strong> the rather complex transitionprocess between the two systems. When the rent control was f<strong>in</strong>ally abolished <strong>in</strong> 1978,Swedish hous<strong>in</strong>g provision had already entered the third phase of the development curve ofhous<strong>in</strong>g provision.The management phaseIn the sixties the hous<strong>in</strong>g shortage <strong>in</strong> the large cities had become a great stra<strong>in</strong> on the SocialDemocrat government, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> 1966 the so-called Million Programme was launched with theaim of construct<strong>in</strong>g one million new dwell<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> the next ten years. Ten years later the goalwas accomplished, <strong>and</strong> from the mid-seventies signs of saturation <strong>in</strong> the form of vacantdwell<strong>in</strong>gs started to s<strong>how</strong> up <strong>in</strong> the market. In this new situation the old ‘provisional’ rentcontrol could f<strong>in</strong>ally be ab<strong>and</strong>oned <strong>in</strong> the whole rental sector. The f<strong>in</strong>al resolution was part ofa large hous<strong>in</strong>g decision of 1974 – <strong>and</strong> was taken almost without political debate. The role ofthe public rents <strong>in</strong> the use-value trials was now given stronger emphasis <strong>in</strong> the Rental Act thanearlier, which aga<strong>in</strong> made it more difficult for private l<strong>and</strong>lords to raise rents <strong>in</strong> situations ofhous<strong>in</strong>g shortage.24 As mentioned the municipal hous<strong>in</strong>g companies is another <strong>in</strong>stitutional pillar under the Swedish hous<strong>in</strong>gregime. Their historical path starts <strong>in</strong> the middle of the 1930s, when it was decided that hous<strong>in</strong>g companies undermunicipal control should be responsible for build<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> manag<strong>in</strong>g hous<strong>in</strong>g estates reserved for household withlow <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> more than two children.25 There was considerable turmoil <strong>in</strong> the decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g process, but this had more to do with the politicalparties try<strong>in</strong>g to position themselves favourably <strong>in</strong> the eyes of the tenants (Bengtsson et al 2006: 124–126).


14Swedish rental corporatism reached it peak <strong>in</strong> 1978 with the Rent Negotiation Act. Until thenthe system of collective negotiations – <strong>in</strong> contrast to the use-value paragraph – had beenvoluntary, but now the right of tenants’ associations to collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g was laid down <strong>in</strong>law. Even though the movement did not get a formal monopoly, it is clear from text of thegovernment bill that units with<strong>in</strong> the National Union of Tenants was expected to represent thetenants <strong>in</strong> all normal situations. The legislation was actually proposed by a non-socialistgovernment, <strong>and</strong> the new law was accepted almost unanimously by the parliament.Even before the new legislation nearly all public rents <strong>and</strong> about half of all private rents hadbeen decided <strong>in</strong> collective negotiations. Supported by the new Rent Negotiation Act, thecollective system was soon implemented <strong>in</strong> almost the whole private sector as well. Thecorporatist control of the rental market was now complete.The retrenchment phaseFrom the eighties a stronger polarisation than before was discernible <strong>in</strong> the political debate,both on hous<strong>in</strong>g policy <strong>in</strong> general <strong>and</strong> on the system of rent-sett<strong>in</strong>g. The political oppositionbecame more <strong>and</strong> more outspoken about the drawbacks of the use-value system. The newnon-socialist government that came <strong>in</strong>to office <strong>in</strong> 1991 launched an overall attack on theSocial Democratic hous<strong>in</strong>g policy – which had largely been decided <strong>in</strong> agreement. In the nextfew years a ‘system shift’ was carried out, <strong>and</strong> a number of economic policy <strong>in</strong>struments wereeither abolished or thoroughly changed. Most prom<strong>in</strong>ently the universal system of statef<strong>in</strong>ance that had been <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong> the 1940s was now ab<strong>and</strong>oned together with most of thestate subsidies, which had been grow<strong>in</strong>g almost out of control s<strong>in</strong>ce the mid-seventies.A reform of the rental policy <strong>and</strong> the use-value system was also on the agenda, but <strong>in</strong> this casethe suggested changes were considerably less far-reach<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>and</strong> certa<strong>in</strong>ly with<strong>in</strong> the generalboundaries of the corporatist system. Nevertheless, when the National Union of Tenantslaunched an attack on ‘market rents’ <strong>and</strong> supported it with op<strong>in</strong>ion polls that <strong>in</strong>dicated that themajority of Swedish tenants were aga<strong>in</strong>st the proposed changes, the government soon backedeven from this position. Eventually only m<strong>in</strong>or adjustments were decided, formallyweaken<strong>in</strong>g the monopoly position of the tenants’ union, but <strong>in</strong> reality without much effect.With the Social Democrats back <strong>in</strong> office from 1992, the system of state f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>and</strong> thegeneral subsidies were not re<strong>in</strong>troduced. The criticism of the use-value system has cont<strong>in</strong>ued<strong>in</strong> recent years, <strong>and</strong> the focus is now on the difficulty to produce new rental hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the<strong>in</strong>ner city of Stockholm with<strong>in</strong> the rent limitations set up by the use-value system. When thegovernment appo<strong>in</strong>ted a commission to <strong>in</strong>vestigate the problem, this was, <strong>how</strong>ever, the resultof a three-party agreement between the two organisations of l<strong>and</strong>lords (private <strong>and</strong> public)<strong>and</strong> the National Union of Tenants. The organisations <strong>in</strong> the rental market were alsorepresented <strong>in</strong> the commission <strong>and</strong> thus guaranteed <strong>in</strong>fluence on the results. It is obvious thatthe corporatist regime <strong>in</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g is still accepted by most political actors, even thoughSwedish corporatism has been strongly weakened <strong>in</strong> other sectors of society.The path dependence of Swedish hous<strong>in</strong>g corporatism – conclusionsWhat can we learn about path dependence from this condensed historical review? Thedevelopment certa<strong>in</strong>ly has some of the features that is characteristic of path dependence. First,the described process has a conspicuous historical logic, from the first <strong>in</strong>stitution of mediation<strong>in</strong> rent conflicts of 1916 up to the full-blown rental corporatism of today that embraces the


15whole market. It is true that history always appears to be more logical when writtenbackwards, but still the self-re<strong>in</strong>forc<strong>in</strong>g sequence of small events is rather strik<strong>in</strong>g. Second,several of the events that <strong>in</strong> h<strong>in</strong>dsight st<strong>and</strong> out as critical junctures on the road to thecorporatist regime are decisions on provisional solutions to acute problems, where possiblelong-term effects are not discussed by the actors <strong>in</strong>volved. Third, decisions at the politicalfocal po<strong>in</strong>ts have often been taken <strong>in</strong> relative consensus, <strong>and</strong> when different alternatives havebeen discussed those have been rather similar to one another. Fourth, when there has been anambition to change the system – most prom<strong>in</strong>ently with the non-socialist government <strong>in</strong> theearly n<strong>in</strong>eties – these ambitions have met with <strong>in</strong>stitutional obstacles that have proved to bedifficult to get by.These observations speak <strong>in</strong> favour of <strong>in</strong>terpret<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>stitutionalisation of Swedish hous<strong>in</strong>gcorporatism as a clear case of path dependence. It rema<strong>in</strong>s to say someth<strong>in</strong>g about the ma<strong>in</strong>elements of this process. What can be said about the critical junctures A, the political focalpo<strong>in</strong>ts B <strong>and</strong> the mechanisms l<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g the events at po<strong>in</strong>t A to the situation at po<strong>in</strong>t B?In accordance with my methodological recommendation above I start with the focal po<strong>in</strong>ts.. Ifwe disregard the <strong>in</strong>troductory phase, the first focal po<strong>in</strong>t along the corporatist path are theformative hous<strong>in</strong>g decisions after World War II, when the municipal hous<strong>in</strong>g companies weregiven their present role <strong>in</strong> the Swedish hous<strong>in</strong>g regime. Rental policy per se was, <strong>how</strong>ever, anissue of non-decision by the time, so the rent control of the war produced a case of‘agenda-sett<strong>in</strong>g path dependence’, where the provisional corporatist mediation could go overunquestioned <strong>in</strong>to the construction phase. The second focal po<strong>in</strong>t is the decision about theRent Negotiation Act of 1978, when the state set up the corporatist system as the rules of thegame <strong>in</strong> the whole rental market. This decision was virtually unanimous, <strong>and</strong> no alternativeswere discussed, so aga<strong>in</strong> the label ‘agenda-sett<strong>in</strong>g path dependence’ would seem appropriate.The third focal po<strong>in</strong>t is the attempt by the non-socialist government <strong>in</strong> 1992 to weakensomewhat the corporatist <strong>in</strong>fluence on the rental market. Though the reforms orig<strong>in</strong>allyproposed were clearly consistent with the prevail<strong>in</strong>g system, they were still discounted <strong>in</strong> thedecision-mak<strong>in</strong>g process. So at this po<strong>in</strong>t we have a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong>agenda-sett<strong>in</strong>g path dependence. 26Thus we have identified three political focal po<strong>in</strong>ts all at po<strong>in</strong>ts of time that <strong>in</strong> other respectsare among the most formative of Swedish hous<strong>in</strong>g policy. Still <strong>in</strong> none of the decision-mak<strong>in</strong>gprocesses was the corporatist system of rental policy politically controversial. In 1946 it is anon-issue, <strong>in</strong> 1978 the reform is decided <strong>in</strong> consensus, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> 1992 only m<strong>in</strong>or change isdecided.The ma<strong>in</strong> conclusion about the critical junctures of the process is that it is difficult to identifyone s<strong>in</strong>gle po<strong>in</strong>t A as be<strong>in</strong>g crucial. E.g. the roots of the Rent Negotiation Act of 1978 can betraced back to the general hous<strong>in</strong>g policy decision of 1974, when the rent control was f<strong>in</strong>allyreplaced by the use-value system. This decision <strong>in</strong> turn can be traced back to the Rental Act of1968, the provisional law of 1956, the new role of municipal hous<strong>in</strong>g companies (<strong>and</strong> thenon-decision on rental policy) of 1946, <strong>and</strong> the decision on rent control of 1942, where thecorporatist adm<strong>in</strong>istrative forms were <strong>in</strong>troduced. The latter decision, aga<strong>in</strong>, may be tracedback to prior forms of <strong>in</strong>terest-based mediation start<strong>in</strong>g as early as 1916, before there evenexisted a national tenants’ movement.26 Had it not been for the professional economists who consistently advocated a completely unregulated rentalmarket it would even have looked like a case of the ‘perceptual’ version.


16This cha<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dicates that with a weak concept of path dependence it is seldom possible toidentify one s<strong>in</strong>gle critical juncture, though <strong>in</strong> this case the ‘provisional’ decision of 1942certa<strong>in</strong>ly st<strong>and</strong>s out more than the others. The large number of critical junctures may alsoreflect that path dependence is particularly prom<strong>in</strong>ent <strong>in</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g due to the physical <strong>and</strong>ideological restra<strong>in</strong>ts discussed above, which would make it more difficult to go back than<strong>in</strong>stigators of provisional policies may realise. The long cha<strong>in</strong> also s<strong>how</strong>s that a focal po<strong>in</strong>t B(e.g. the reforms of 1946) may at the same time be a po<strong>in</strong>t A <strong>in</strong> relations to subsequent po<strong>in</strong>tsB.What are the mechanisms that have restricted actors at the political focal po<strong>in</strong>ts? In aperspective of contextual rational action these mechanisms should affect either (1) the set ofactors <strong>and</strong> their relative power, (2) the alternatives perceived by those actors or (3) the actors’preference orders between those alternatives. If we look closer at the latest focal po<strong>in</strong>t of1992, the puzzle is why non-socialist politicians, who were strongly committed to a ‘systemshift’ <strong>in</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g policy, <strong>and</strong> with no str<strong>in</strong>gs to the tenants’ movement, did not take theopportunity to come to grips with the corporatism <strong>in</strong> the rental sector.To give a def<strong>in</strong>ite answer we would need to go even closer to real actors than has beenpossible <strong>in</strong> this study. From a little distance, <strong>how</strong>ever, it seems that a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of power,legitimacy <strong>and</strong> efficiency has been at work. The corporatist system has given power to boththe tenants’ <strong>and</strong> the l<strong>and</strong>lords’ organisations, <strong>and</strong> their participation is crucial to theimplementation of the policy <strong>in</strong> the market arena. And while the use-value system is more orless a necessary prerequisite of the strong position of the tenants’ unions, the l<strong>and</strong>lords’organisations also appear to f<strong>in</strong>d the system generally both efficient <strong>and</strong> effective.Furthermore op<strong>in</strong>ion polls from the time s<strong>how</strong>ed consistently that the system was legitimateamong tenants <strong>in</strong> general – <strong>and</strong> probably among voters (cf. Bengtsson <strong>and</strong> Rothste<strong>in</strong> 1997:282–83). Together with the apparent acceptance of the system by l<strong>and</strong>lords, this legitimacymay have made the political cost of chang<strong>in</strong>g the system to someth<strong>in</strong>g less corporatist <strong>and</strong>more market-based seem too high. F<strong>in</strong>ally a general conversion from one set of <strong>in</strong>stitutions toanother would have resulted <strong>in</strong> transaction costs at all levels.One f<strong>in</strong>al remark. Hous<strong>in</strong>g organisations can be seen as act<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> three different but<strong>in</strong>terrelated arenas: <strong>in</strong>ternal, market <strong>and</strong> political (cf. Bengtsson 1995). The ma<strong>in</strong> focus herehas been on the political arena, but as we have seen the path of the corporatist hous<strong>in</strong>g policyruns <strong>in</strong> parallel – <strong>and</strong> sometimes <strong>in</strong>tersects with – other processes <strong>in</strong> the other arenas. Themost critical juncture <strong>in</strong> the organisational arena was probably the decision of the NationalUnion of Tenants <strong>in</strong> the thirties to follow the collaborative path of peaceful negotiations, <strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong> the market arena the huge production of multi-family public rental hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the years ofthe Million Programme. If we want to compare, <strong>in</strong> counterfactual perspective, the pathdependence of Swedish corporatist rental policy with correspond<strong>in</strong>g paths of non-corporatistrental policies of other countries all three arenas must be considered.ReferencesArnott, R, 1987, ‘Economic Theory <strong>and</strong> Hous<strong>in</strong>g’, pp 959–88 <strong>in</strong> Mills, E S (ed.) H<strong>and</strong>book of Regional <strong>and</strong>Urban Economics, Vol. II. Urban Economics, Amsterdam: North-Holl<strong>and</strong>.Bengtsson, B, 1991, ‘The Crisis of Public Hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Sweden – Economic Reality or Organizational Myth?’Sc<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>avian Hous<strong>in</strong>g & Plann<strong>in</strong>g Research, Vol. 8: 113–27.Bengtsson, B, 1994, ‘Swedish Rental Policy – A Complex Superstructure with Crack<strong>in</strong>g Foundations’Sc<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>avian Hous<strong>in</strong>g & Plann<strong>in</strong>g Research, Vol. 11: 182–89.Bengtsson, B, 1995, ‘Hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Game-Theoretical Perspective’, Hous<strong>in</strong>g Studies, Vol. 10: 229–43.


Bengtsson, B, 2001, ‘Hous<strong>in</strong>g as a Social Right: Implications for Welfare State Theory’, Sc<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>avian PoliticalStudies, Vol. 24: 255–75.Bengtsson, B, (ed.), Annaniassen, E, Jensen, L, Ruonavaara, H <strong>and</strong> Sve<strong>in</strong>sson, J R, 2006, Varför så olika?Nordisk bostadspolitik i jämför<strong>and</strong>e historiskt ljus [Why so Different? Nordic Hous<strong>in</strong>g Policy <strong>in</strong> ComparativeHistorical Light], Malmö: Égalité.Bengtsson, B <strong>and</strong> Rothste<strong>in</strong>, B, 1997, ‘Precisionsbombn<strong>in</strong>gens problem – välfärdsstaten och bostadspolitiken’[The Problem of Precision Bomb<strong>in</strong>g – The Welfare State <strong>and</strong> Hous<strong>in</strong>g Policy], pp 246–98 <strong>in</strong> Andersson, Å.E.(ed.), Bostadsmarknaden på 2000-talet, Stockholm: SNS Förlag.Bengtsson, B <strong>and</strong> Somerville, P, 2002 “Underst<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g Contextualised Rational Action – Authors’ Response”,Hous<strong>in</strong>g Theory <strong>and</strong> Society, Vol. 19: 148–52.Collier, R B <strong>and</strong> Collier, D, 1991, Shap<strong>in</strong>g the Political Arena. Critical Junctures, the Labor Movement, <strong>and</strong>Regime Dynamics <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America, Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton: Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton University Press.Elster, J, 1989, Nuts <strong>and</strong> Bolts for the Social Sciences, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Hall, P A <strong>and</strong> Taylor, R C R, 1996, ‘Political Science <strong>and</strong> the Three New Institutionalisms’, Political Studies,Vol. 44: 936–57.Hoogerwerf, A, 1990, ’Reconstruct<strong>in</strong>g Policy Theory’, Evaluation <strong>and</strong> Program Plann<strong>in</strong>g, Vol. 13: 285–91.Hughes, T P, 1983, Networks of Power. Electrification of the Western Society 1880–1930, Baltimore: JohnHopk<strong>in</strong>s University Press.Jensen, L, 1995, ‘Udvikl<strong>in</strong>gstræk ved det almennyttige beboerdemokrati i Danmark 1900–1990’ [TheDevelopment of Residents’ Democracy <strong>in</strong> Danish Public Hous<strong>in</strong>g 1900–1990], pp 225–55 <strong>in</strong> Madsen, M,Nielsen, H J <strong>and</strong> Sjöblom, G (eds), Demokratiets mangfoldighed: Tendenser i dansk politik, Copenhagen:Forlaget Politiske Studier.Kemeny, J, 1995, From Public Hous<strong>in</strong>g to the Social Market: Rental Policy Strategies <strong>in</strong> ComparativePerspective, London: Routledge.Kemeny, J <strong>and</strong> Lowe, S, 1999, ‘Schools of Comparative Hous<strong>in</strong>g Research: From Convergence to Divergence’,Hous<strong>in</strong>g Studies, Vol. 13: 161–76.Lipset, S M <strong>and</strong> Rokkan, S, 1967, ‘Cleavage Structures, Party Systems, <strong>and</strong> Voter Alignments: An Introduction,pp 1–64 <strong>in</strong> Lipset, S M <strong>and</strong> Rokkan, S (eds), Party Systems, <strong>and</strong> Voter Alignments: Cross-NationalPerspectives, New York: Free Press.Lukes, S, Power. A Radical View, Bas<strong>in</strong>gstoke & London: MacMillan.Mahoney, J, 2000, ‘<strong>Path</strong> <strong>Dependence</strong> <strong>in</strong> Historical Sociology’, Theory <strong>and</strong> Society, Vol. 29: 507–48.Meyerson, P–M, Ståhl, I <strong>and</strong> Wickman, K, 1990, Makten över bostaden [The Power over Hous<strong>in</strong>g], Stockholm:SNS Förlag.North, D C, 1990, Institutions, Institutional Change <strong>and</strong> Economic Performance, New York: CambridgeUniversity Press.Offe, C, 1985, Disorganized Capitalism. Contemporary Transformations of Work <strong>and</strong> Politics, Cambridge:Polity Press.Oxley, M <strong>and</strong> Smith, J, 1996, Hous<strong>in</strong>g Policy <strong>and</strong> Rented Hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Europe, London: E & FN Spon.Peters, B G, 1999, Institutional Theory <strong>in</strong> Political Science. The ‘New Institutionalism’, London & New York:P<strong>in</strong>ter.Pierson, P, 2000 ‘Increas<strong>in</strong>g Returns, <strong>Path</strong> <strong>Dependence</strong> <strong>and</strong> the Study of Politics’, American Political ScienceReview, Vol. 94: 251–67.Pierson, P, 2003, Politics <strong>in</strong> Time. <strong>History</strong>, Institutions <strong>and</strong> Social Analysis, Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton: Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton UniversityPress.Putnam, R D, 1993, Mak<strong>in</strong>g Democracy Work. Civic Traditions <strong>in</strong> Modern Italy, Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton: Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton UniversityPress.Rothste<strong>in</strong>, B, 1998, Just Institutions <strong>Matter</strong>. The Moral <strong>and</strong> Political Logic of the Universal Welfare State,Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Ruonavaara, H, 1992, ‘Types <strong>and</strong> Forms of Hous<strong>in</strong>g Tenure: Towards Solv<strong>in</strong>g the Comparison/TranslationProblem’, Sc<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>avian Hous<strong>in</strong>g & Plann<strong>in</strong>g Research, Vol. 10: 3–20.Ruonavaara, H, 2005, ‘How Divergent Hous<strong>in</strong>g Institutions Evolve: A Comparison of Swedish TenantCo-operatives <strong>and</strong> F<strong>in</strong>nish Shareholders´ Hous<strong>in</strong>g Companies’, Hous<strong>in</strong>g, Theory <strong>and</strong> Society, Vol. 22: 213–236.Schell<strong>in</strong>g, T C (1960) 1980, The Strategy of Conflict, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Somerville, P <strong>and</strong> Bengtsson, B, 2002, ‘Constructionism, Realism <strong>and</strong> Hous<strong>in</strong>g Theory’ Hous<strong>in</strong>g, Theory <strong>and</strong>Society, Vol. 19: 121–36.Stahl, K, 1985, ‘Microeconomic Analysis of Hous<strong>in</strong>g Markets: Towards a Conceptual Framework’, <strong>in</strong> Stahl, K,(ed.) Microeconomic Models of Hous<strong>in</strong>g Markets, Berl<strong>in</strong> & Heidelberg: Spr<strong>in</strong>ger-Verlag.Thelen, K, 1999, ‘Historical Institutionalism <strong>in</strong> Comparative Politics’, Annual Review of Political Science 2:369–404.17


Torgersen, U, 1987, ‘Hous<strong>in</strong>g: The Wobbly Pillar of the Welfare State’, pp 116–26 <strong>in</strong> Turner, B, Kemeny, J <strong>and</strong>Lundqvist, L J (eds) Between State <strong>and</strong> Market: Hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the Post-Industrial Era, Sc<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>avian Hous<strong>in</strong>g &Plann<strong>in</strong>g Research, Supplement 1.Turner, B, 1988, ‘Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Aspects of Negotiated Rents <strong>in</strong> the Swedish Hous<strong>in</strong>g Market’, Journalof Real Estate F<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>and</strong> Economics, Vol. 1: 257–76.Williamson, P, 1989, Corporatism <strong>in</strong> Perspective. An Introductory Guide to Corporatist Theory, London: Sage.18

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!