11.07.2015 Views

Policy Impacts on Deforestation Lessons Learned ... - The REDD Desk

Policy Impacts on Deforestation Lessons Learned ... - The REDD Desk

Policy Impacts on Deforestation Lessons Learned ... - The REDD Desk

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesExecutive SummaryNati<strong>on</strong>al and internati<strong>on</strong>al efforts within thelast few decades to reduce forest loss, while havingsome impact, have failed to substantially slow the lossof the world’s forests. Forest loss, i.e., deforestati<strong>on</strong> andforest degradati<strong>on</strong>, is widespread and accounts for 12%–17% of the world’s greenhouse gas (GHG) emissi<strong>on</strong>s.Global c<strong>on</strong>cern about climate change and the realizati<strong>on</strong>that reduced emissi<strong>on</strong>s from deforestati<strong>on</strong> and degradati<strong>on</strong>(<strong>REDD</strong>) can play a role in climate change mitigati<strong>on</strong>make it critical to learn from our past experiences withpolicies to reduce forest loss.Within the UN Framework C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> ClimateChange (UNFCCC), negotiators are actively c<strong>on</strong>sideringways to include incentives for <strong>REDD</strong> and other forestcarb<strong>on</strong> activities in any post-2012 treaty. In parallel, theU.S. C<strong>on</strong>gress is developing proposals for a l<strong>on</strong>g-termclimate policy that includes incentives for <strong>REDD</strong>, andpossibly other internati<strong>on</strong>al forest carb<strong>on</strong> activities.Such policies may mobilize new funds for forest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>,including for addressing drivers of deforestati<strong>on</strong>and forest degradati<strong>on</strong> in developing countries.Climate-related incentives for <strong>REDD</strong> are likely to beperformance-based, i.e., to emphasize the measurement,reporting, and verificati<strong>on</strong> of all results. <strong>The</strong> implementati<strong>on</strong>of this emphasis, al<strong>on</strong>gside the introducti<strong>on</strong> ofnew financial incentives, could increase such policies’impacts <strong>on</strong> forest loss relative to the past.<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> effectiveness, efficiency, and equity can increaseif we learn less<strong>on</strong>s from the past about what drives andwhat inhibits deforestati<strong>on</strong> and degradati<strong>on</strong>. It is inthe interest of any <strong>REDD</strong> program to understand whathas worked in reducing deforestati<strong>on</strong> and degradati<strong>on</strong>and what has not, as well as the reas<strong>on</strong>s for observeddifferences in outcomes. Investments and policies canthen more effectively embrace and extend success whilereducing risks of further failures.This report aims to provide less<strong>on</strong>s to inform U.S. andinternati<strong>on</strong>al policymakers by analyzing dominant influences<strong>on</strong> deforestati<strong>on</strong> and degradati<strong>on</strong>. We study not<strong>on</strong>ly forest-focused policies, but also other policies thatdirectly or indirectly influence forest loss, all in light ofrelevant n<strong>on</strong>policy factors such as trends in commodityprices. We provide examples of previous policies todraw less<strong>on</strong>s from successes and failures, then link thoseobservati<strong>on</strong>s about the past to the decisi<strong>on</strong>s currentpolicymakers must so<strong>on</strong> make within <strong>on</strong>going climatepolicy deliberati<strong>on</strong>s.Drivers of Forest LossAgriculture is the primary driver of tropical deforestati<strong>on</strong>.When tropical forest is cleared, land is almostalways c<strong>on</strong>verted to crops and/or pasture. Thus deforestati<strong>on</strong>is driven by expected benefits of producing staplefoods, for local and/or nati<strong>on</strong>al markets, as well as internati<strong>on</strong>alcommodities including biofuels, timber, andfiber. Incentives result from the local and global demandfor commodities. Pressures are exacerbated by governmentsupport for agriculture, from road investment toprovisi<strong>on</strong> of cheap credit and easier access to land titleafter clearing. Yet <strong>on</strong>ly some determinants can be shiftedby policymakers within the c<strong>on</strong>text of <strong>REDD</strong> policies.For example, rising demand for soy may be outside thepurview of <strong>REDD</strong> policy, yet research to facilitate substitutesoy producti<strong>on</strong> in n<strong>on</strong>forest regi<strong>on</strong>s may be a relatedand relevant policy.<strong>The</strong> limited profitability of sustainable forest managementalso causes forest loss. Low timber prices discouragel<strong>on</strong>g-run management. So do the lack of access tocredit for forest users and the lack of secure resourcetenure, e.g., a lack of secure land tenure in the relativelyfew forest areas that are not government-owned.Services provided by forests (e.g., species habitat) oftenfail to provide revenues that could affect land-use decisi<strong>on</strong>s.Yet policies that fund <strong>REDD</strong> could change thesedefaults, leading local actors to value service producti<strong>on</strong>and making it profitable to manage forests for storageof carb<strong>on</strong> as well as forest joint products such as specieshabitat.While logging and fuelwood collecti<strong>on</strong> directly drive<strong>on</strong>ly forest degradati<strong>on</strong>, not deforestati<strong>on</strong>, they mayalso have indirect impacts within the tropics. In particular,the forest may be more accessible after processesof degradati<strong>on</strong> and thus more likely to be cleared foragriculture.Internati<strong>on</strong>al Forest PoliciesMany internati<strong>on</strong>al efforts have aimed to reduce forestloss. With few excepti<strong>on</strong>s, large-scale c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>of tropical forest cannot be attributed to these efforts.Few initiatives effectively influenced underlying driversof deforestati<strong>on</strong>, such as infrastructural and agriculturalpolicy, while others did not even identify them. Substantialor sustained improvements to rural ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>sand development practices were also not partof many programs. Yet there are cases where targeted,Nicholas Institute5


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativeswell-managed internati<strong>on</strong>al efforts catalyzed domesticpressure for reform or realigned political and ec<strong>on</strong>omicinterests to achieve tropical forest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>. Belowwe indicate elements, from the suite of past efforts, thatmay play a role within <strong>REDD</strong>.Loan C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ality. C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ality up<strong>on</strong> reform withinforestry has risen in recent decades. C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al loansattach specific reforms—improved law enforcement,expanded parks areas, ec<strong>on</strong>omic policy changes—tolending from governments and multilateral financialinstituti<strong>on</strong>s. Yet c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ality often failed to imposethe sweeping policy changes that had been envisi<strong>on</strong>ed.Still, evidence of targeted, successful c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al loansexists—particularly for envir<strong>on</strong>mental issues. Loanscatalyzed reform when the interests of lenders and keylocal stakeholders were aligned. Critical issues includereforms’ c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong>s to nati<strong>on</strong>al or local developmentpriorities.D<strong>on</strong>or Coordinati<strong>on</strong>. D<strong>on</strong>or coordinati<strong>on</strong> aims to increasethe effectiveness and efficiency of official developmentassistance (ODA) by reducing duplicati<strong>on</strong>, inefficiencies,and the administrative burden <strong>on</strong> recipient countries,while in additi<strong>on</strong> increasing the strategic targetingof aid. Yet d<strong>on</strong>or fragmentati<strong>on</strong>, a technical assistancefocus, and poor policy selecti<strong>on</strong> have persisted. Evengood coordinati<strong>on</strong> may not yield benefits where governmentsdo not share d<strong>on</strong>ors’ goals, where c<strong>on</strong>tracts cannotbe used effectively, and where officials can capturefunds. For forests, while key past efforts have fallen shortof expectati<strong>on</strong>s (TFAP), broader “d<strong>on</strong>or coordinati<strong>on</strong>”encompasses varied instituti<strong>on</strong>al arrangements, some ofwhich are promising (PPG7, NREG).Debt Relief. Debt to foreign countries and to internati<strong>on</strong>albanks may encourage forest loss. It may restrictenforcement budgets and may lead governments toraise revenues to service debt through timber royaltiesor taxes <strong>on</strong> agricultural exports. During the late 1990s,e.g., Ind<strong>on</strong>esia may have faced internati<strong>on</strong>al pressureto increase exports of timber, paper pulp and palm oil.Debt-for-nature swaps try to address this by reducinginternati<strong>on</strong>al debt, typically in exchange for establishinga c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> trust fund within the debtor nati<strong>on</strong>.For instance under the 1998 Tropical Forest C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>Act, by 2007 the U.S. reduced the debts of twelveLatin American countries plus Botswana. Yet a causallink to forest loss is hard to establish. Impact evaluati<strong>on</strong>sare few. One 2007 U.S. government evaluati<strong>on</strong> of a debtswapinitiative in El Salvador did not quantify forestimpacts but suggested that forest outcomes fell short ofoverambitious targets.Demand Management. This policy shares with debt reliefthe advantage of external c<strong>on</strong>trol. In principle, if theworld wants less forest loss, then it can lower demandsfor destructive outputs. Most industrial roundwoodharvested in developing countries is c<strong>on</strong>sumed there,but the trade in logs and processed products is significant,particularly via China, and trade in pulp productsand agricultural commodities is large. This suggests arole for demand-side interventi<strong>on</strong>. Its impacts will begreatest when it can also shape practices and standardswithin supplier countries. Efforts range from c<strong>on</strong>sumercampaigns to certificati<strong>on</strong> to treaties and policies, e.g.,trade policy harm<strong>on</strong>izati<strong>on</strong> per CITES, the 2003 FLEGTActi<strong>on</strong> Plan to prevent illegal imports to the EU, or the2008 amendments to the U.S. Lacey Act. Yet all thesemust stand up to market forces. Ghana’s experience from1979 to the 1990s shows that inadequate policies will failto dampen demand.Domestic Forest PoliciesVaried nati<strong>on</strong>al and subnati<strong>on</strong>al initiatives have aimed toc<strong>on</strong>serve forests. <strong>The</strong>ir primary aim—reducing deforestati<strong>on</strong>as well as forest degradati<strong>on</strong>—has typically been<strong>on</strong>ly partially achieved, due to limits <strong>on</strong> how key driversof forest loss were addressed. <strong>The</strong> impacts of protectedareas and ecosystem services payments have been limited,due to the fact that they both tend to be locatedwhere forest threats are relatively low, although impacts<strong>on</strong> forest degradati<strong>on</strong> are also important while not beingas well understood. C<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s by their very natureshould manage pressure for clearing, yet the details ofsuch c<strong>on</strong>tracts (much as for the ecopayments c<strong>on</strong>tracts)are critical if the dominant local land-use incentives areto shift significantly. Decentralizati<strong>on</strong> does not automaticallyaddress any of these issues, but if incentives arealigned, then in some situati<strong>on</strong>s more local c<strong>on</strong>trol overdecisi<strong>on</strong> making could generate <strong>REDD</strong> and improvewelfare.Protected Areas. Protected areas are the most comm<strong>on</strong>explicit forest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> policy and have increasedsubstantially over the past two decades. As they tend tobe in areas currently facing relatively low threat, theymay lower deforestati<strong>on</strong> less than expected and less thanis typically assumed (see studies of Costa Rica, BrazilianAmaz<strong>on</strong>, Mexico, and all areas globally). Betterdata could improve the evidence c<strong>on</strong>cerning potentiallyhigher impacts <strong>on</strong> degradati<strong>on</strong>, while for deforestati<strong>on</strong>good data show that impacts vary across a landscape.Where threat is high and enforcement is str<strong>on</strong>g, therecan be significant avoided deforestati<strong>on</strong>, such as the relativelybig impacts of Chico Mendes Extractive Reserve inthe Amaz<strong>on</strong> near the Interoceanic Highway.Nicholas Institute6


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesEcopayments. Payments for ecosystem services (e.g.,water quality, habitat, or carb<strong>on</strong> storage) can rewardowners for limiting land use to c<strong>on</strong>serve forests. Yet mostprograms are voluntary. Owners may offer their leastproductive land and be paid to retain forest that wouldremain in the absence of policy. Costa Rica’s pi<strong>on</strong>eeringand inspirati<strong>on</strong>al program faced very low threat of deforestati<strong>on</strong>and was not designed to target threat. Most paidforest would have remained standing without a payment.Looking ahead, planners could target clearing threat.Costa Rica’s invaluable “learning laboratory” also showsthe importance of the details of program design. Afterthe policy was already in place, still an evoluti<strong>on</strong> overtime and space in how payments were allocated reduceda bias towards low threat, raising payment impact <strong>on</strong>deforestati<strong>on</strong>.C<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s. Logging is often d<strong>on</strong>e through private c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>sin government-owned forests. Often large foreignfirms bid for c<strong>on</strong>tracts stating a volume or area toharvest in some period. Firms pay fees, or “royalties,”usually based <strong>on</strong> area or volume, and revenues can besignificant. C<strong>on</strong>tracts can specify envir<strong>on</strong>mentally sensitivemethods. Yet poor design and enforcement meangovernments fail to capture revenue, protect habitat,exclude illegal loggers, and enforce methods. For <strong>REDD</strong>,governments could reduce carb<strong>on</strong> emissi<strong>on</strong>s within timberc<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s, e.g., through additi<strong>on</strong>al enforcement ofimproved practices and the exclusi<strong>on</strong> of illegal loggers. Ac<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong> model could also be employed in the designof <strong>REDD</strong>, as suggested by cases of nati<strong>on</strong>al governmentsseeking internati<strong>on</strong>al bidders to support c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> offorest that would otherwise be managed under resourcec<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s. In Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, <strong>REDD</strong> projects establish newlegal rights to carb<strong>on</strong> via ecosystem restorati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>sthat preempt timber or oil palm.Decentralizati<strong>on</strong>. Most tropical forests are owned bystates. Milli<strong>on</strong>s who live in forests have <strong>on</strong>ly “use” rightsand cannot block others’ exploitati<strong>on</strong> of the resources<strong>on</strong> which they depend. Yet recently governments havedevolved forest ownership and/or management resp<strong>on</strong>sibilitiesto local instituti<strong>on</strong>s, and some evidence suggestsdecentralizati<strong>on</strong> can be effective in reducing forestloss. Some indigenous and community-managed areaswithin the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong> have been more effectivethan state-managed areas in blocking deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Yetfor this approach to generate <strong>REDD</strong>, critical instituti<strong>on</strong>alc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s must be in place. Local instituti<strong>on</strong>s must havesecure rights to own and to manage the forest (e.g., toenter into c<strong>on</strong>tracts for carb<strong>on</strong>), financial incentives forforest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>, and the state’s support (c<strong>on</strong>tractenforcement at the least). Local instituti<strong>on</strong>s are alsomore effective when both transparent and downwardlyaccountable.Other Domestic PoliciesAdjusting other domestic policies with significanteffects <strong>on</strong> forest loss may be as important for <strong>REDD</strong> asdomestic forest policies. Yet little has been d<strong>on</strong>e to ourknowledge. Below we describe development policies thataffect deforestati<strong>on</strong> and we suggest such policies couldbe adjusted.Infrastructure Policies. Transport costs matter for agriculture,logging, and fuelwood collecti<strong>on</strong>. New road investmentsraise access, lower transport cost, and often yieldmore ec<strong>on</strong>omic output as well as more forest loss. Critically,roads’ impacts vary across space. New roads investmentsappear to increase forest loss less when locatedin already developed areas—with prior forest loss androads. Thus, the total forest impact of a road policy isaffected by road network design (analogous results mayapply for energy transport). In additi<strong>on</strong>, some haveclaimed that forest loss from such investments can belowered when c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> is sequenced or integratedwith other policies (e.g., tenure, local services), raisingquality of life while preserving natural wealth. An examplecould be park buffers around roads to imitate howsome reserves are functi<strong>on</strong>ing.Agricultural Policies. Agricultural commodity prices andproducti<strong>on</strong> costs are important drivers of deforestati<strong>on</strong>.Many governments subsidize agriculture through outputprices (import tariffs <strong>on</strong> competing products, subsidizedprocessing) and input prices (interest rates, fertilizercosts), as well as lower taxes. <strong>The</strong>y also facilitate tenurefor cleared land and help to reduce other risks like pestsand disease through investments in research and development.Without support for forests, these encourageclearing. If they link with col<strong>on</strong>izati<strong>on</strong>, impacts rise dueto migrati<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>cerning biofuels, if they are cultivated<strong>on</strong> croplands then clearing may expand into forests, asthe supply of the displaced agricultural commodity (e.g.,soy) falls and thus its price will rise. Biofuels subsidiesfor lands not in agricultural producti<strong>on</strong>, in c<strong>on</strong>trast,could reduce forest loss.Land Tenure. Legal systems that award squatters’ rightsand then title to those who clear forest have l<strong>on</strong>g promoteddeforestati<strong>on</strong>. Even clearing for unprofitable usemay allow the acquisiti<strong>on</strong> of title and facilitate credit orresale. <strong>The</strong> lack of secure tenure matters too since a riskof losing <strong>on</strong>e’s forests through expropriati<strong>on</strong> reducesincentives for l<strong>on</strong>g-term sustainable management. It isdifficult for individuals, and even communities, to stopNicholas Institute7


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativesexpropriati<strong>on</strong> where timber trespass can occur. Becausedefending tenure is costly, when owners choose landuses they c<strong>on</strong>sider site protecti<strong>on</strong> costs within relativereturns from uses such as grazing cattle versus managedforest or reserves. Carb<strong>on</strong>-based payments couldincrease the rents to holding forests but must overcomehigher protecti<strong>on</strong> costs for forest. Those will be moreimportant when government enforcement tends to bepoor due to budget c<strong>on</strong>straints, remoteness of forestsand corrupti<strong>on</strong>.Corrupti<strong>on</strong>. Government corrupti<strong>on</strong> is present in developingcountries with large forest areas. It is not easilyc<strong>on</strong>trollable and is a complex, multifaceted problem thatis a c<strong>on</strong>straint for <strong>REDD</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tracts. In forestry sectors, itusually takes <strong>on</strong>e of two forms: large firms with politicalpower may influence government policies or choicesabout c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s, at early stages of the process; orsmaller firms may bribe state officials to overlook a c<strong>on</strong>tract’sstipulati<strong>on</strong>s during processing, milling, or exporting.Even with efforts to restrict such activities, <strong>REDD</strong>payments could simply increase equilibrium bribes andtransfer wealth to illegal loggers and officials whoseobjectives do not align with the governments promoting<strong>REDD</strong>. While it may seem attractive to overlook corrupti<strong>on</strong>and hope that carb<strong>on</strong> payments will help to reduceforest loss despite these issues, costly anti-corrupti<strong>on</strong>measures up fr<strong>on</strong>t may be better than leaving corruptactors unchecked.Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong>Neither too easy nor too hard. Two opposite schools ofthought are emerging regarding the role of internati<strong>on</strong>alforest carb<strong>on</strong> and <strong>REDD</strong> in U.S. and global climatepolicy. One asserts that opportunities to reducecarb<strong>on</strong> emissi<strong>on</strong>s are cheap and also abundant. Thus, ifthey generate carb<strong>on</strong> credits, those credits could “flood”cap-and-trade programs and reduce the incentive toinvest in emissi<strong>on</strong>s reducti<strong>on</strong> within rich countries. <strong>The</strong>other <strong>on</strong>e asserts that reducing global deforestati<strong>on</strong> is sodaunting that significant reducti<strong>on</strong> of this type is nearlyimpossible.<strong>The</strong> first view is guided in part by the noti<strong>on</strong> that the costof stopping deforestati<strong>on</strong> exactly equals the opportunitycost of the alternative land use (e.g., revenues generatedby agriculture). In this view, these revenues may also beperceived often to be low (though they are not alwaysso and can be very high) which suggests that c<strong>on</strong>servingforests is relatively cheap. This view ties in with c<strong>on</strong>cernsthat errors in negotiated emissi<strong>on</strong> baselines couldyield many credits not backed by emissi<strong>on</strong> reducti<strong>on</strong>s.<strong>The</strong> sec<strong>on</strong>d view appears to be guided by the failures ofprevious efforts to reduce deforestati<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>cernsthat many countries still lack the governance capacity toeffectively implement new such policy programs.Reality lies in between these extremes. <strong>The</strong>re are opportunitiesto avoid deforestati<strong>on</strong> in the tropics at low costcompared to other efforts to reduce GHG emissi<strong>on</strong>s.Yet claims about the opportunities immediately availablehave likely been overstated. Actual costs of reducingdeforestati<strong>on</strong> include costs to reform land tenure,to distribute payments, and to establish, manage, andm<strong>on</strong>itor protected areas. C<strong>on</strong>tinued demand for woodand agricultural products, populati<strong>on</strong> pressures, weakgovernance, and other instituti<strong>on</strong>al factors are limits <strong>on</strong>short-run reducti<strong>on</strong>s in deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Thus, comm<strong>on</strong>lyused measures of opportunity costs do not indicate typicalcosts, but rather a minimum or lower-bound <strong>on</strong> thecost of implementing <strong>REDD</strong>.This realizati<strong>on</strong> could lead <strong>on</strong>e towards the sec<strong>on</strong>d view,and indeed reviewing the results of past efforts to halttropical deforestati<strong>on</strong> is sobering. Many policies did nottarget drivers behind deforestati<strong>on</strong> and thus were largelyineffective. In many cases, this was due to insufficientc<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> of how to target lands under real threatof deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Interventi<strong>on</strong>s also failed due to limitedlocal engagement and insufficient stakeholder participati<strong>on</strong>,while weak governance, corrupti<strong>on</strong>, and lack ofland titles and law enforcement created further barriersto significant land-use change. In additi<strong>on</strong>, previous programsalmost universally lacked self-evaluati<strong>on</strong> mechanisms,which limited learning and thus modificati<strong>on</strong>.However as we have discussed above, many features ofpast policies could be drastically improved up<strong>on</strong> in thefuture.Designing policy for <strong>REDD</strong> feasibility. <strong>The</strong> prospect ofrewards for internati<strong>on</strong>al forest carb<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>under future U.S. and internati<strong>on</strong>al climate policieshas brought new energy to the pursuit of protecti<strong>on</strong> oftropical forests. Yet the debate has not been informedby close c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> of the nature of the internati<strong>on</strong>aland domestic policies required if <strong>REDD</strong> is to play a significantrole. We believe that internati<strong>on</strong>al and domesticinterventi<strong>on</strong>s can lower deforestati<strong>on</strong> with both the supportof local actors and smart policy design.Past failures suggest there are potential benefits fromprogram requirements that are broad enough to encouragelocally appropriate interventi<strong>on</strong>s. For instance, ifcomprehensive m<strong>on</strong>itoring captures GHG emissi<strong>on</strong>sreducti<strong>on</strong>s, then requirements and incentives can bebased <strong>on</strong> that aggregate outcome and many other detailsmay be left to local actors better placed to significantlyNicholas Institute8


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativesand sustainably shift relevant local processes. This avoidsdifficulty in m<strong>on</strong>itoring and rewarding local process.Generally, c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with those affected by these policiescan aid in the development of effective and sustainablepolicy.Such policies may not immediately come to pass, andeven if the above describes future internati<strong>on</strong>al regimesaccurately, still domestic actors will have to decide howto try to lower GHG emissi<strong>on</strong>s in order to capture forestincentive payments. For these reas<strong>on</strong>s, there is value inlearning further from both the successes and the failuresof the many previous types of forest interventi<strong>on</strong>. Drawingfrom all the above: we can ask skeptically whetherloan c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ality is likely to work without changedlocal practices; we can str<strong>on</strong>gly encourage bringing thelocally forest-dependent peoples into discussi<strong>on</strong>s; wecan shift protected areas and ecopayments towards areasof higher forest threat and impact; and we can evaluatewhether carb<strong>on</strong>-based payments may justify, evenin local development terms al<strong>on</strong>e, shifts in roads or insubsidies.Moving forward:• the U.S., in c<strong>on</strong>cert with internati<strong>on</strong>al actors, canhelp forested countries with the costs of c<strong>on</strong>servingforest carb<strong>on</strong>, including with costs of strengtheningthe relevant instituti<strong>on</strong>s• internati<strong>on</strong>al forest carb<strong>on</strong> policies can adoptperformance indicators so that incentives can beeffectively applied; outcomes m<strong>on</strong>itoring and evaluati<strong>on</strong>will permit <strong>on</strong>going learning• forested countries can rethink not <strong>on</strong>ly forestpolicy but also how agriculture and infrastructurepolicies affect forests; preferred strategies will differas a functi<strong>on</strong> of local c<strong>on</strong>text• internati<strong>on</strong>al and domestic actors can re-examinewhether acti<strong>on</strong>s work well in c<strong>on</strong>cert, e.g., policyinfluences <strong>on</strong> commodity demands versus subsidiesfor agriculture or biofuelsIn summary, it is possible to identify critical deforestati<strong>on</strong>drivers and to align the local, regi<strong>on</strong>al, nati<strong>on</strong>al, andinternati<strong>on</strong>al incentives within many forest settings. Climateprotecti<strong>on</strong> provides a new way for forest protecti<strong>on</strong>to c<strong>on</strong>tribute, and to succeed, if we learn less<strong>on</strong>s fromthe past.Nicholas Institute9


Introducti<strong>on</strong>Nati<strong>on</strong>al and internati<strong>on</strong>al efforts within thelast few decades to reduce forest loss, while havingsome impact, have failed to substantially slow the lossof the world’s forests. Forest loss, i.e., both deforestati<strong>on</strong>and forest degradati<strong>on</strong>, is widespread, and it accounts for12%–17% of the world’s greenhouse gas (GHG) emissi<strong>on</strong>s.Global c<strong>on</strong>cern about climate change, al<strong>on</strong>gsidethe realizati<strong>on</strong> that reducing emissi<strong>on</strong>s from deforestati<strong>on</strong>and degradati<strong>on</strong> (<strong>REDD</strong>) can play a role in climatechange mitigati<strong>on</strong>, makes it critical to learn from ourpast experiences of forest loss.Within the UN Framework C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> ClimateChange (UNFCCC), negotiators are actively c<strong>on</strong>sideringways to include incentives for <strong>REDD</strong> and other forestcarb<strong>on</strong> activities in any post-2012 treaty. In parallel, theU.S. C<strong>on</strong>gress is developing proposals for a l<strong>on</strong>g-termclimate policy which includes incentives for <strong>REDD</strong> and,possibly, other internati<strong>on</strong>al forest carb<strong>on</strong> activities.Such policies may mobilize new funds for forest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>,including for addressing drivers of deforestati<strong>on</strong>and forest degradati<strong>on</strong> in developing countries.Climate-related incentives for <strong>REDD</strong> are likely to beperformance-based, i.e., to emphasize the measurement,reporting, and verificati<strong>on</strong> of all results. <strong>The</strong> implementati<strong>on</strong>of this emphasis, al<strong>on</strong>gside the introducti<strong>on</strong> ofnew financial incentives, could increase policies’ impacts<strong>on</strong> forest loss relative to the past.More generally, policy effectiveness, efficiency and equitycan increase if we learn less<strong>on</strong>s from the past about whatdrives and what inhibits deforestati<strong>on</strong> and degradati<strong>on</strong>.It is in the interest of any <strong>REDD</strong> program to understandwhat has worked in reducing forest loss and degradati<strong>on</strong>and what has not, as well as the reas<strong>on</strong>s for thosedifferences in outcomes. Investments and policies thencan more effectively embrace and extend success whilereducing risks of further failures.This report aims to provide such less<strong>on</strong>s to inform U.S.and internati<strong>on</strong>al policymakers by analyzing the dominantinfluences up<strong>on</strong> deforestati<strong>on</strong> and degradati<strong>on</strong>. Westudy forest-focused and other policies that directly orindirectly influence forest loss, all in light of n<strong>on</strong>policyfactors such as trends in commodity prices. We provideexamples of previous policies and draw less<strong>on</strong>s fromtheir successes and failures, then link those observati<strong>on</strong>sabout the past to the key decisi<strong>on</strong>s that current policymakersmust so<strong>on</strong> make within <strong>on</strong>going climate policydeliberati<strong>on</strong>s. We set out by highlighting activities thatdominate deforestati<strong>on</strong> and forest degradati<strong>on</strong>, i.e., agriculture,logging, and fuelwood collecti<strong>on</strong>, and then wedistinguish three categories of policies that could produce<strong>REDD</strong>. Next, Secti<strong>on</strong>s 1–3 provide evidence <strong>on</strong> theimpacts of a number of past experiences within each ofthe three categories. We c<strong>on</strong>clude with broader less<strong>on</strong>slearned.Agriculture, Logging, and FuelwoodDominate Forest LossAgricultureAgricultural expansi<strong>on</strong> is the primary driver of deforestati<strong>on</strong>within the tropics. When a tropical forest iscleared, land is almost always c<strong>on</strong>verted to agriculturalcrops and/or to pasture. Thus the deforestati<strong>on</strong> is drivenby the expected benefits of c<strong>on</strong>verting forest land forproducti<strong>on</strong> of staple foods, for local as well as nati<strong>on</strong>almarkets, and of internati<strong>on</strong>al commodities includingbiofuels, timber, and fiber. <strong>The</strong> incentives are beingcreated by local and global demands for commodities.Pressures are exacerbated by government policies thatsupport agricultural expansi<strong>on</strong>, from road investment toprovisi<strong>on</strong> of cheap credit and easier access to land titleswhen lands are cleared. Only some determinants can beshifted by policymakers. Others do not suggest <strong>REDD</strong>policies. For example, rising global demand for soy maybe outside the purview of <strong>REDD</strong> policy, while research<strong>on</strong> soy cultivars for n<strong>on</strong>forest regi<strong>on</strong>s, for instance, couldexplicitly be a policy choice.Logging and Fuelwood Collecti<strong>on</strong><strong>The</strong> limited profitability of sustainable forest managementalso causes forest loss. Low prices for timber, inpart due to unsustainable and often illegal logging practices(e.g., Rhodes et al. 2006), discourage l<strong>on</strong>g-run management.So do the lack of access to credit and the lack ofsecure tenure for forest users in the (many fewer) forestareas that are not government owned. Critical servicesprovided by forests (e.g., species habitat and water quality)often fail to provide any revenues that could affectland-use decisi<strong>on</strong>s. Yet climate policies that fund <strong>REDD</strong>could change these defaults and lead local actors to valueadditi<strong>on</strong>al forest services, making it profitable to managethe forest for the many local and global goods thatforests provide, including the storage of forest carb<strong>on</strong>.Nicholas Institute10


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesLogging, Fuelwood Collecti<strong>on</strong>, andAgriculture 1While logging and fuelwood collecti<strong>on</strong> directly drive<strong>on</strong>ly forest degradati<strong>on</strong>, not deforestati<strong>on</strong>, they may alsohave additi<strong>on</strong>al indirect impacts within the tropics. Inparticular, the forest may be more accessible after processesof degradati<strong>on</strong> and thus more likely to be clearedfor agriculture.Three <str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> Categories Produce <strong>REDD</strong>Efforts to c<strong>on</strong>serve forests must be viewed in light of theprocesses that are driving deforestati<strong>on</strong> and forest degradati<strong>on</strong>.Forest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> policies (for instance, protectedareas or payment for ecosystem services) attemptto impose or to induce changes in land use decisi<strong>on</strong>s.Such changes have a cost—the loss of income from producti<strong>on</strong>and sale of crops. Put another way, the driversof forest loss are the determinants of the local privatebenefits of clearing and degradati<strong>on</strong> of forest. Thus thesedrivers and associated benefits are critical to predictingland use and inducing <strong>REDD</strong>.An important corollary is that whether local decisi<strong>on</strong>sare taken by private or public actors, these decisi<strong>on</strong>s haveoften ignored spillover effects, i.e., impacts of land uses<strong>on</strong> others’ welfare. Thus, in the absence of an interventi<strong>on</strong>that makes such c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong>s, neither GHG emissi<strong>on</strong>snor other external effects of deforestati<strong>on</strong> or forestdegradati<strong>on</strong> affect the local land-use choices that yieldforest loss. Land-use choice might well, however, shift ifcarb<strong>on</strong>-based incentives were created.For <strong>REDD</strong>, any such incentives must overcome the factorsthat lead to deforestati<strong>on</strong> and forest degradati<strong>on</strong>,i.e., agriculture, logging and the collecti<strong>on</strong> of fuelwood. 2<strong>The</strong>se include biophysical land characteristics such assoil fertility, forest type, and climate. <strong>The</strong>y are not shiftedby policy, yet understanding their influences will help toidentify interventi<strong>on</strong>s with greatest forest impact.those determinants of land-use choices which can beshifted, and specifically three categories of <strong>REDD</strong>-generatingpolicies. <strong>The</strong> first two are “c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>” or policiesthat explicitly target the forest: Secti<strong>on</strong> 1 examinesinternati<strong>on</strong>al policies, and Secti<strong>on</strong> 2 studies forest policyin forested countries. Secti<strong>on</strong> 3 presents forest-relevantn<strong>on</strong>forest policy, i.e., domestic policies in forested countriesthat do not target forests but could affect forest loss.Thus within forest-targeted policies, Secti<strong>on</strong> 1 and Secti<strong>on</strong>2 distinguish interventi<strong>on</strong>s implemented by internati<strong>on</strong>alactors such as loan c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ality, d<strong>on</strong>or coordinati<strong>on</strong>,debt relief, and commodity demand management(all discussed in Secti<strong>on</strong> 1) from the interventi<strong>on</strong>s thatare implemented by nati<strong>on</strong>al or subnati<strong>on</strong>al actors inforested countries such as protected areas, ecopayments,forest c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s and decentralizati<strong>on</strong> (all discussed inSecti<strong>on</strong> 2). We make this external-vs.-internal distincti<strong>on</strong>even if the latter interventi<strong>on</strong>s could potentially anddo receive internati<strong>on</strong>al support. From the external andmacro-scale “forest acti<strong>on</strong> plans” to internal and microscaleecoservices c<strong>on</strong>tracts, we review what has and hasnot worked. In analyzing reas<strong>on</strong>s for success and failure,we develop suggesti<strong>on</strong>s about which policies couldeffectively generate <strong>REDD</strong>. Secti<strong>on</strong> 3 then c<strong>on</strong>tinues inthis same vein but c<strong>on</strong>cerning clearly distinct policies,i.e., shifts in formulati<strong>on</strong> or implementati<strong>on</strong> of policiesthat do not explicitly focus <strong>on</strong> forests but rather up<strong>on</strong>development more generally such as infrastructure, agriculture,tenure and corrupti<strong>on</strong>. Given multiple ways toachieve development goals such as increased producti<strong>on</strong>and employment, in principle incentives for <strong>REDD</strong>could lead local policymakers to choose paths whichinvolve a lowering of emissi<strong>on</strong>s.Other determinants can be shifted. For example, variouspublic and private choices that affect the access to forestand the costs of transport to and from forested areascould be adjusted. For <strong>REDD</strong> policy, we will focus up<strong>on</strong>1 Of course other activities matter too. In specific sites both mineral extracti<strong>on</strong>and the reservoirs behind dams directly cause forest loss, although the c<strong>on</strong>troversiesover these activities may be more significant than their direct impacts up<strong>on</strong>the forest. Indirect impact also matter, though. <strong>The</strong>y may attract migrants wholog, collect fuelwood, or c<strong>on</strong>vert forest land to agriculture. Also, in some regi<strong>on</strong>s,mining may generate significant demand for charcoal and, in turn, degradati<strong>on</strong>and even deforestati<strong>on</strong>.2 Broad reviews are in Kaimowitz and Angelsen 1998, Geist and Lambin 2001,and Chomitz’s 2006 “At Loggerheads” volume.Nicholas Institute11


1. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Forest PoliciesMany internati<strong>on</strong>al efforts have aimed toreduce deforestati<strong>on</strong> and to increase transparencyin the forest sector. With few excepti<strong>on</strong>s, large-scale c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>of tropical forest cannot be attributed to theseefforts. Few initiatives effectively influenced underlyingdrivers of deforestati<strong>on</strong>, such as infrastructural and agriculturalpolicy, while others did not even identify them.Substantial or sustained improvements to rural ec<strong>on</strong>omicc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s and development practices were als<strong>on</strong>ot part of many programs. Yet there are cases wheretargeted, well-managed internati<strong>on</strong>al efforts catalyzeddomestic pressure for reform or realigned political andec<strong>on</strong>omic interests to achieve tropical forest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>.Below we indicate elements, from the suite of pastefforts, that may play a role within <strong>REDD</strong>.1.1. Loan C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ality<strong>The</strong> amount of loans and development assistance c<strong>on</strong>tingentup<strong>on</strong> forestry reform has risen in recent decades,with significant sums spent to create and improve forestmanagement. C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al loans attach specificreforms—improved law enforcement, expanded parksareas, ec<strong>on</strong>omic policy changes—to lending from governmentsand multilateral financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s.<strong>The</strong>re has been c<strong>on</strong>troversy over whether such lending—imposingbenchmarks and requirements as a c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>for loans—is the best way to spur envir<strong>on</strong>mentalreforms. <strong>The</strong> effectiveness of this approach has beenlimited by corrupti<strong>on</strong> and insufficient coordinati<strong>on</strong> withstakeholders ranging from village associati<strong>on</strong>s to largetimber firms. Transforming local instituti<strong>on</strong>s is complexand slow, particularly when the external pressure is notmatched with internal support for reform. Many loancovenants thus have overreached, asserting sweepingreforms without c<strong>on</strong>necting the external c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s inquesti<strong>on</strong> to nati<strong>on</strong>al or local development priorities.Between 1971 and 1990, most l<strong>on</strong>g-term aid carried littleor no effective c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ality (Bo<strong>on</strong>e 1995). Only underrelatively recent pressure from d<strong>on</strong>or governments andinternati<strong>on</strong>al financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s were such c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>sapplied to enforce accountability. C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>alityincreased in the 1990s to influence unsustainable forestrypractices and promote good governance in countriessuch as Cambodia, Philippines, and Ind<strong>on</strong>esia. Itwas, to some extent, an alternative to the binding multilateraltreaties that proved hard to establish and enforce.Multilateral lending and macroec<strong>on</strong>omic policies wereseen as a new way to address issues such as deforestati<strong>on</strong>(Keohane and Levy 1996).In many cases, these loans failed to impose the sweepingpolicy changes they envisi<strong>on</strong>ed. <strong>The</strong> Internati<strong>on</strong>al M<strong>on</strong>etaryFund points out in an internal review (referringgenerally to macroec<strong>on</strong>omic policy adjustments) that“tightly budgeted c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al assistance programs neverbring about reforms” since narrow domestic interestsand uneven access to informati<strong>on</strong> raise the cost of lendingprograms and hinder implementati<strong>on</strong> (Mayer andMourmouras 2005).Yet evidence of more targeted, successful c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>alloans exists—particularly around envir<strong>on</strong>mental issues.For the most part, successful loans catalyzed the domesticappetite for reform when the interests of lenders andrecipient countries were aligned. Domestic interestswere critical in explicitly c<strong>on</strong>necting reforms to nati<strong>on</strong>alor local development priorities. External pressureadvances these reforms as l<strong>on</strong>g as there is “commitmentto the reform agenda and engagement with stakeholdersto communicate [the] strategy” (Ross 1996). Severalexamples are examined below and shared c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s forsuccess are described.1.1.1. Case EvidenceMany instances of ineffective lending programs existbut some programs have produced envir<strong>on</strong>mental governancesuccesses that may be replicable elsewhere. Twodecades of research and reviews by instituti<strong>on</strong>s suggestthat there are some comm<strong>on</strong> features of successful lendingoperati<strong>on</strong>s and loans in the c<strong>on</strong>text of the forestrysector (Keohane and Levy 1996):• political power was not primarily aligned with loggingor other extractive industries• they advocated for targeted forest policy changesinstead of l<strong>on</strong>g-term, comprehensive instituti<strong>on</strong>alreforms that may be potentially unc<strong>on</strong>nected tothe purpose of the loan itself• they maintained and expanded domestic supportfor forestry sector reform am<strong>on</strong>g the public actors,as well as bey<strong>on</strong>d them, including by communicatingpolicy strategies clearly and explicitlyWhen some or all of these c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s are not in place,the already challenging task of reform becomes miredin the political process with few or powerless advocatesin the recipient government. <strong>The</strong>se failures are generallyNicholas Institute12


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativescomprehensive view of forest protecti<strong>on</strong> possible, sincethe Agriculture Ministry is not part of NREG eventhough agriculture is an important driver of deforestati<strong>on</strong>.Further, some other government agencies thatinfluence key drivers, such as transport and infrastructure,are not fully engaged. This may change as NREG isbuilding an interministerial body to which the <strong>REDD</strong>Steering Committee will report. Such coordinati<strong>on</strong> willlikely be critical to its success.1.2.2. Looking AheadAn effective <strong>REDD</strong> framework will require coordinati<strong>on</strong>of support for many quite distinct sectors. <strong>The</strong> benefitsof harm<strong>on</strong>izati<strong>on</strong> of their acti<strong>on</strong>s and of the provisi<strong>on</strong> ofresources to support such acti<strong>on</strong>s may mean that d<strong>on</strong>orcoordinati<strong>on</strong> plays a central role in <strong>REDD</strong>’s effectivenessand efficiency.A critical less<strong>on</strong> from the past is to avoid purely forest-sectorand/or purely d<strong>on</strong>or-driven strategies. Anyacti<strong>on</strong>s that affect deforestati<strong>on</strong> should be productivelyharm<strong>on</strong>ized within an overall <strong>REDD</strong> strategy. Effectiveand efficient <strong>REDD</strong> is likely to involve infrastructural aswell as agricultural and other sectors within an overallstrategy while providing a way for d<strong>on</strong>ors to align objectiveswith all of them.A sec<strong>on</strong>d key point is that d<strong>on</strong>or coordinati<strong>on</strong> in of itselfis not enough for broad stakeholder buy-in. <strong>The</strong> latterinvolves c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerning the needs of all criticallocal groups, raising the need to rec<strong>on</strong>cile local andnati<strong>on</strong>al as well with external goals. Forest-dependentcommunities are key stakeholders in this process. InTFAP, civil society demanded c<strong>on</strong>sultative processesand the battle over broad c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>tributed tothe overall failure of the initiative. Within PPG7, localcivil society was c<strong>on</strong>sulted about land demarcati<strong>on</strong> andprotecti<strong>on</strong>s. NREG tries to build creative platforms forcoordinati<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>. In sum, the less<strong>on</strong>s fromTFAP and PPG7 and early NREG evidence suggest thatfuture successes are dependent <strong>on</strong>:• collaborati<strong>on</strong> between domestic governments andd<strong>on</strong>ors• accountability to all the parties through transparentreporting• integrati<strong>on</strong> of all relevant sectors’ c<strong>on</strong>cerns• seeking out d<strong>on</strong>ors’ comm<strong>on</strong> interests with localstakeholders1.3. Debt ReliefGiven the significance of forested countries’ domesticpolitics above, c<strong>on</strong>cerning debt relief we note that it isexternal actors who are the lenders and can forgive adebt. 8 Yet whether debt relief effectively targets deforestati<strong>on</strong>remains an open questi<strong>on</strong>.Debt relief involving c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> agreements, or “debtfor-natureswaps,” are “transacti<strong>on</strong>(s) between twoor more parties to enable c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> or the provisi<strong>on</strong>of envir<strong>on</strong>mental services” (Deac<strong>on</strong> 1997). <strong>The</strong>semay be three-party swaps, usually with a c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>group purchasing debt to commercial banks or creditorgovernment that was renegotiated then selling it tothe debtor country for more than the NGO paid but lessthan the sec<strong>on</strong>dary market value. <strong>The</strong> difference can beused to fund c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>. Swaps may also be bilateral(government-to-government).This approach gained popularity in the last two decadeswith such transacti<strong>on</strong>s generating over US$117 milli<strong>on</strong>in local currency for c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> projects, includingthrough the purchase of about US$168 milli<strong>on</strong> in debt(face value) for US$49 milli<strong>on</strong> between 1987 and 2006(Sheikh 2006). It relies <strong>on</strong> external instituti<strong>on</strong>s willing toforgo funds in return for protecti<strong>on</strong> of the forest.Even without direct c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s labeled for c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>,debt relief may increase forest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> asdebt may encourage deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Large governmentdebts to foreign countries and internati<strong>on</strong>al banks mayencourage tropical countries to raise revenues to coverdebt service through timber royalties or taxes <strong>on</strong> agriculturalexports. Looking globally, Kahn and McD<strong>on</strong>ald(1995) find a relati<strong>on</strong>ship between debt levels and ratesof deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Since many factors drive forest loss,especially at the scale of a country, clear causal linksare difficult to establish between debt reducti<strong>on</strong> andlower resource extracti<strong>on</strong> (Sheikh 2006). In the 1990s,8 That is not true of all externally determined financial influences. <strong>The</strong> termsof trade facing a country also affect deforestati<strong>on</strong>. When a country’s currencyis devalued, its exports become less expensive for others. Devaluati<strong>on</strong> is oftenrecommended for indebted countries that need to increase export revenue andis also associated with increased deforestati<strong>on</strong>. This may be a direct result ofincreased demand for agricultural exports. It may also be the result of increaseddemand for timber exports, which leads timber companies to expand loggingroads further into the forest, improving access for other agents. Simulati<strong>on</strong>models, such as computable general equilibrium models, generally c<strong>on</strong>firmthese effects, showing that devaluati<strong>on</strong>, trade liberalizati<strong>on</strong>, and lower agriculturalexport taxes increase deforestati<strong>on</strong> (Kaimowitz and Angelsen [1998]: 64).Nepstad et al. (2006a) show that over decades the amount of soy exported fromthe Amaz<strong>on</strong> tracks the Brazilian real’s rate of exchange with other currencies.Cattaneo (2001) analytically formalizes the potential importance of this ideausing a general equilibrium model. Thus here a financial factor (previously wenoted biophysical c<strong>on</strong>stants like slope of land) is unlikely to be shifted for <strong>REDD</strong>rati<strong>on</strong>ales, i.e., is in the category of a c<strong>on</strong>straint <strong>on</strong> planning and impacts of<strong>REDD</strong>, including as a source of uncertainty.Nicholas Institute17


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativeshowever, Ind<strong>on</strong>esia may have been pressured by internati<strong>on</strong>alfinancial instituti<strong>on</strong>s to increase exports of timber,paper pulp and palm oil to, am<strong>on</strong>g other things, servicedebt payments.Al<strong>on</strong>g these lines, some studies in the last decade thatsuggest government debt or budget c<strong>on</strong>straints createincentive for government to designate greater harvestingarea and permit more deforestati<strong>on</strong> to raise revenue(Kahn and McD<strong>on</strong>ald 1995; Amacher 1999). Debt servicealso can tie up existing government revenue, makingforest enforcement impossible for central governmentslocated up to many hundreds of miles away fromforest resources. Amacher et al. (2008b) find this wouldexacerbate illegal logging and the influence of bribesup<strong>on</strong> operati<strong>on</strong> of c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong> and policy design. In thissetting, “<strong>REDD</strong> transfers” could reduce incentives forgovernments to increase harvest c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s.1.3.1. Case EvidenceWe distinguish two avenues by which debt relief mayaffect deforestati<strong>on</strong>. <strong>The</strong> indirect approach wouldreduce debt burdens in order to relieve financial pressureto increase exports and repay loans, which mightor might not affect deforestati<strong>on</strong>. <strong>The</strong> direct approachwould involve a form of earmarking the m<strong>on</strong>ies forgivenexplicitly for c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> by developing countries (anopti<strong>on</strong> that then takes <strong>on</strong> some of the characteristics ofc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ing loans <strong>on</strong> less forest loss).Currently debt relief often is being used directly as a toolfor c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>, i.e., the sec<strong>on</strong>d approach, especially asimplemented by the United States and Germany. Mostearly transacti<strong>on</strong>s that involved country debt that wasowed to commercial banks, in additi<strong>on</strong>, were administeredby n<strong>on</strong>governmental c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>s.Other debt-for-nature initiatives involved official (public)debt and were administered by creditor governmentsdirectly with debtor governments.<strong>The</strong> United States’ 1998 Tropical Forest C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>Act (TFCA) authorized exchanges of developing countrydebt for deposits to tropical forest funds. <strong>The</strong> interestearned (and perhaps the principal) supports grants fortropical forest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> projects. Eligible c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>projects include (1) establishing, maintaining,and restoring forest parks and protected reserves, (2)increasing the capacity of pers<strong>on</strong>nel to manage reserves,(3) developing and supporting communities near or intropical forests, (4) developing sustainable ecosystemand land management, and (5) identifying the medicinaluses of tropical forest plants and their products. Ifthe activities supported were not going to occur in theabsence of these deposits of funds, this direct approachcan have impacts.By 2006, 11 countries had established agreements toreduce their debts to the U.S. and generate US$136.5 milli<strong>on</strong>in local currency over 12–26 years for tropical forestc<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>. By 2009, the U.S. had used the TFCA toreduce debts of nine Latin American countries in additi<strong>on</strong>to Bangladesh, Botswana, and the Philippines, oftenwith c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s from major envir<strong>on</strong>mental organizati<strong>on</strong>s.For example, in 2002 the U.S. government forgaveUS$6.6 milli<strong>on</strong> of Peru’s debt with c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s fromthe Nature C<strong>on</strong>servancy, the World Wildlife Fund, andC<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> Internati<strong>on</strong>al after Peru agreed to commitabout US$10.6 milli<strong>on</strong> of debt savings to c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>over 12 years. <strong>The</strong> U.S. funds al<strong>on</strong>e ostensibly enabledpreservati<strong>on</strong> of more than 27.5 milli<strong>on</strong> acres of rainforest(TNC 2009). Working with the Club of Paris, Peruhas also substantially reduced its debt with Germany,Canada, Finland, the Netherlands, and Switzerland,putting part of those funds (~US$57 milli<strong>on</strong>) in envir<strong>on</strong>mentalprograms with involvement of NGOs likePROFONANPE.Debt relief terms can appeal to tropical forested countries’ec<strong>on</strong>omic self interests as well as their goals forc<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>. Ind<strong>on</strong>esia rejected earlier internati<strong>on</strong>alproposals for debt relief in favor of a deal that was distinguishedby its clear incentive structures, feasible objectives,and discreti<strong>on</strong> about spending <strong>on</strong> forest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>.To be eligible for this debt swap, a country was<strong>on</strong>ly required to have the Ministry of Forestry submit aforest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> proposal with budget support fromthe Ministry of Finance plus an independent audit of theMinistry of Forestry’s management of the project. <strong>The</strong>most recent swap under TFCA is expected to reduceInd<strong>on</strong>esia’s debt payments to the U.S. by US$30 milli<strong>on</strong>.It involves internati<strong>on</strong>al and nati<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>mentalorganizati<strong>on</strong>s (C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> Internati<strong>on</strong>al and YayasanKeanekaragaman Hayati Ind<strong>on</strong>esia). <strong>The</strong> German governmentalso agreed to swap about EUR 12.5 milli<strong>on</strong> inloans for EUR 6.25 milli<strong>on</strong> of forest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> programsin Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, al<strong>on</strong>g with a sec<strong>on</strong>d program (EUR106 milli<strong>on</strong>) also financing forestry programs (Purnomoet al. 2007). Yet for this and many other examples citedabove, impacts <strong>on</strong> forest have not yet been shown.1.3.2. Looking AheadDrawing any causal linkage between debt and deforestati<strong>on</strong>currently is difficult. Evaluati<strong>on</strong>s of the impact ofdebt swaps are few. A 2007 U.S. evaluati<strong>on</strong> of an initiativein El Salvador did not quantify forest impact butsuggested that results fell short of its ambitious targets.Nicholas Institute18


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesHowever, debt swaps c<strong>on</strong>tinue to attract d<strong>on</strong>or and hostcountry support, labeling milli<strong>on</strong>s of dollars for l<strong>on</strong>gtermforest-c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> projects. Generally, this hasbeen viewed as a success by c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>sand debtor governments because of the funds generatedfor c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> efforts.While sec<strong>on</strong>dary market and other c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s affectthe appeal of debt-for-nature swaps looking forward,for c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> purposes it is attractive to invest overa l<strong>on</strong>g time horiz<strong>on</strong> (Sheikh 2006). Ultimately, though,successes depend <strong>on</strong> “the viability of the programmes[and] strength of the organizati<strong>on</strong>s and communitiesimplementing the programmes [with] swap proceeds”(Resor 1997).1.4. Demand ManagementDemand management shares with debt relief the advantageof significant external c<strong>on</strong>trol. Thus if the worldwants less deforestati<strong>on</strong>, in principle we can just stopdemanding destructive output. Demand for pulp, paper,food, biofuel, and other agricultural products drivesdeforestati<strong>on</strong> and destructive (and often illegal) logging.At a global level, though, most industrial roundwoodharvested in developing countries is ultimately c<strong>on</strong>sumedwithin developing countries. Yet significant porti<strong>on</strong>is traded to developed countries in the form of logsor processed products, particularly via China. <strong>The</strong>re isalso a very large internati<strong>on</strong>al trade in pulp products andbiofuels. <strong>The</strong> volume and value of these commodities islarge, including an annual trade of timber (US$224.3billi<strong>on</strong>), soy (US$22 billi<strong>on</strong>) and palm oil (US$12.7 billi<strong>on</strong>)(Daviet 2009). Such trade linkages suggest a role forglobal demand-side interventi<strong>on</strong>s to reduce ec<strong>on</strong>omicincentives for producti<strong>on</strong> of commodities <strong>on</strong> the forestfr<strong>on</strong>tier. Impact will, though, be limited if programsfocus solely up<strong>on</strong> the c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> within developedcountries. However, pressures from internati<strong>on</strong>al buyersalso can shape the industry practices and the standardswithin supplier countries.Demand-side efforts may take many forms, ranging fromloosely organized c<strong>on</strong>sumer campaigns and related (butincreasingly more influential) voluntary certificati<strong>on</strong>systems through to treaties and government policies. Allof these must involve coordinating or influencing a largenumber of internati<strong>on</strong>al actors using coercive enforcement(if by a state) or simply informati<strong>on</strong> or publicity,from civil society or from the government. Examplesinclude the harm<strong>on</strong>izati<strong>on</strong> of trade policy, such as tradec<strong>on</strong>trols for CITES-listed species 9 ; the European Uni<strong>on</strong>’s9 C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Trade in Endangered Species.2003 FLEGT Acti<strong>on</strong> Plan to prevent illegal importsinto the EU; the 2008 amendments to the United States’Lacey Act expanding import restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> plants andplant products, as well as disclosure and informati<strong>on</strong>campaigns that influence public opini<strong>on</strong> or reveal theactual envir<strong>on</strong>mental impacts of commercial products.Demand-side measures may be critical to the successof <strong>REDD</strong>. Experience in tropical countries has shownthat measures to slow deforestati<strong>on</strong> without addressingdemand face serious complicati<strong>on</strong>s; e.g., the implicati<strong>on</strong>sof high demand may hinder law enforcement andthwart the formati<strong>on</strong> of policies regulating forest assets.Yet demand-side measures themselves must be robustenough to stand up to market forces. Demand measuressuch as wood processing fees or log export bans may notmatter if demand is sufficiently high (or other distorti<strong>on</strong>ssuch as corrupti<strong>on</strong> are present). Ghana’s experience withsuch measures from 1979 to the 1990s shows inadequatepolicies will fail to dampen market demand and must becomplemented by supply-side c<strong>on</strong>trol (Richards 1995).This has already been recognized in the climate debate,and direct support for countries seeking to address illegallogging are included in the U.S. American Climateand Energy Security bill (H.R. 2545), passed by theHouse in June 2009 (Daviet 2009).1.4.1. Case Evidence1.4.1.1. Private-sector initiatives (campaigns/certificati<strong>on</strong>).Campaigns to date have highlighted “the hamburgerc<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong>” to clearing in Central America from beefc<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> in the U.S. as well as identifying “forestfriendly”commodities such as certified timber, n<strong>on</strong>timberforest products, and “bird-friendly” coffee or cacao.<strong>The</strong>se were all attempts to shift demand away from producti<strong>on</strong>that causes deforestati<strong>on</strong> or towards producti<strong>on</strong>that maintains forest cover. While such campaigns haverarely shifted global prices significantly, due to the size ofmarkets and number of buyers unwilling to adjust theirpurchasing habits, they have created market niches forcertified producers by changing the procurement practicesof some major c<strong>on</strong>sumers, especially those withbrand names to protect.Both governments and NGOs have emphasized theimportance of full informati<strong>on</strong> and disclosure of whereand how products are supplied. For example, the ForestFootprint Disclosure Project recently launched withsupport of the UK government reveals how companies’“operati<strong>on</strong>s and supply chains are impacting forestsworldwide, and what is being d<strong>on</strong>e to manage thoseimpacts resp<strong>on</strong>sibly” (M<strong>on</strong>gabay.com 2009). NGOs havepursued a similar approach, providing informati<strong>on</strong> toNicholas Institute19


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativesc<strong>on</strong>sumers as part of their strategy for persuading companiesto adopt certificati<strong>on</strong>.In Brazil, NGOs appear to be having some success influencingdemand for beef and soybeans from the Amaz<strong>on</strong>.For example, in 2006 agricultural giants like Cargill,Archer Daniels Midland Co. and Bunge Ltd., as well asFrance’s Dreyfus and Brazilian-owned Amaggi, agreed toa moratorium <strong>on</strong> clearing forest for soybeans after pressureand publicity from groups like Greenpeace (haltingclearing in some high-deforestati<strong>on</strong> areas by 2008,according to Greenpeace and the Brazilian VegetableOils Industry Associati<strong>on</strong> [AP 2008]). Nepstad et al.(2009) suggest that such “market exclusi<strong>on</strong> of deforesterscould be strengthened through government measuresthat penalize companies and banks that indiscriminatelydo business with Amaz<strong>on</strong> farmers and cattle ranchers.”Boycotts by themselves have some fundamental weaknesses:freeriding and coordinati<strong>on</strong> failures clearly areendemic, facing such decentralized private choices withclear spillovers, given the inherent tradeoff betweenopportunity cost of participating and the potential tohurt the targeted firm (Delacote 2009). Further, it isusually difficult to scale up boycotts to nati<strong>on</strong>al policybecause of WTO rules.N<strong>on</strong>etheless, such campaigns can have effects and maywork in tandem with other policy approaches. Forinstance, calls for tropical timber boycotts in late 1980sare widely believed to have been an impetus for thedevelopment of sustainable forest certificati<strong>on</strong> systems.Supporters of certificati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tinue to use negative publicityand boycotts targeted at companies (and their supplychains) to encourage commitments to purchase certifiedproducts. Sasser et al. (2006) point out that firmsmay resp<strong>on</strong>d “strategically to NGO demands in order tomaintain c<strong>on</strong>trol over their instituti<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>ment.”In particular, in the U.S., forest product firms createdtheir own certificati<strong>on</strong> standard rather than join the ForestStewardship Council (FSC).FSC and competing forest certificati<strong>on</strong> systems appearto modestly boost relative profitability through reducedmarketing costs, lower risks associated with forestfriendlygoods, preferential access to buyers and, sometimes,price premia. Other commodities such as coffeeand cacao are being certified as well, and anotherincreasingly well-known example is the Roundtable <strong>on</strong>Sustainable Palm Oil (RSPO). Bitzer et al. (2008) note:“Over recent years, the use of standards and voluntarycodes of c<strong>on</strong>duct in combinati<strong>on</strong> with certificati<strong>on</strong>sschemes has spread significantly in many agro-commodities.Observers even speak of the emergence of a globalaudit culture originating in Northern industrializedcountries and stressing inspecti<strong>on</strong>, measurement andcertificati<strong>on</strong>.” Such a disseminati<strong>on</strong> of like efforts createsnew dialogues and demand for participating producers.Certificati<strong>on</strong> has its weaknesses. To the extent that it isbeing applied mostly to “parallel producti<strong>on</strong> systems”that affect <strong>on</strong>ly small fracti<strong>on</strong> of area used for a crop,its impacts could well be limited. Few countries targetedfor <strong>REDD</strong> have large areas of certified forests: <strong>on</strong>ly 15%of FSC-certified forests are located in the tropics andsub-tropics (FSC 2009), with 217 certificates issued byOctober 2009 (Cashore et al. 2006a). Thus the costs ofcertificati<strong>on</strong> may be outweighing the benefits, whichhave remained limited to rewards in markets versus, forinstance, any public “push” (e.g., in forest sector governance)that would support adopti<strong>on</strong> (Ebeling and Yasué2009).Further, to the extent that multiple certificati<strong>on</strong> systemsexist and compete for the minds of the world’s c<strong>on</strong>sumers,they may undermine the effectiveness of the moststringent <strong>on</strong>es, at least. It is even possible this could yielda “race to the bottom” (Bitzer et al. 2008; Raynolds et al.2007). On the other hand, Sasser et al. (2006) and Overdevest(2009) suggest that competiti<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g forest certificati<strong>on</strong>systems has actually led to a general ratchetingup of forest management standards, all with third-partyoversight.Another weakness of certificati<strong>on</strong> is that many initiativesfail to engage with stakeholders in producer countries(Partzsch 2009; Bitzer et al. 2008). Some c<strong>on</strong>sider the FSCto have been effective in engaging stakeholders throughnati<strong>on</strong>al working groups. For instance: “. . . when certificati<strong>on</strong>does not itself prove to be the answer to thesequesti<strong>on</strong>s, the debate has been effective. <strong>The</strong>re are casesof working group deliberati<strong>on</strong>s being taken into otherpolicy arenas. At the very least, the work of such groupshas had an excellent capacity development effect” (Bassand Guéneau 2007). Taking this point further, since governmentspredominantly own the forest within developingcountries and most industrial roundwood is c<strong>on</strong>sumeddomestically in those countries, for large impactscertificati<strong>on</strong> likely requires local buy-in.While such private-sector initiatives may not yet havehad c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> and stewardship effects as large as initiallyimagined, policies to complement such schemes—both <strong>on</strong> the demand and <strong>on</strong> the supply side—maydramatically change this picture. C<strong>on</strong>trasting Boliviaand Ecuador, for instance, suggests that this approach“can be successful . . . where governments have limitedgovernance capacity” but this relies <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>siderableNicholas Institute20


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativesgovernment c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s, such as to enforce forestrylaws, to offer financial incentives for certified forestry,to impose land-tenure security, and to encourage largescale,vertically integrated commercial forest operati<strong>on</strong>s(Ebeling and Yasué 2009).1.4.1.2. Reciprocal trade c<strong>on</strong>trols. Reciprocal and unilateraltrade c<strong>on</strong>trols—laws in importing nati<strong>on</strong>s that providea legal basis for the m<strong>on</strong>itoring and seizure of illicittrade—are increasingly used to complement both exportingnati<strong>on</strong>s’ domestic laws and internati<strong>on</strong>al rules suchas those under the C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Trade inEndangered Species (CITES). States can establish regi<strong>on</strong>alenforcement protocols by harm<strong>on</strong>izing major importingand exporting customs policies, giving governments bettertools to c<strong>on</strong>trol the commerce in wildlife, especially intimber, across their borders (Laws<strong>on</strong> 2005).<strong>The</strong> listing of ramin under the CITES complementeddomestic law and gave foreign governments the abilityto police trade. This is believed to have significantlyreduced illegal trade in the species from Ind<strong>on</strong>esia (Laws<strong>on</strong>2005). A sec<strong>on</strong>d well-documented example is Ind<strong>on</strong>esia’sban <strong>on</strong> exports of round and squared logs in 2001.This was complemented by a prohibiti<strong>on</strong> against importsof such logs in Malaysia. Reports of illegal log smugglingdropped dramatically. <strong>The</strong> Envir<strong>on</strong>mental Investigati<strong>on</strong>Agency cites it as <strong>on</strong>e of a “few cases where any of thecommitments <strong>on</strong> this topic made by governments in theregi<strong>on</strong> over the past few years has been shown to havehad any real impact <strong>on</strong> the ground” (Laws<strong>on</strong> 2005).Yet the ban does not cover wood products or sawn timber,i.e., other products may still be smuggled unimpeded.Harm<strong>on</strong>ized paperwork requirements wouldhelp, as border officials from two sides can then compareimport/export records. Without more complete reciprocalc<strong>on</strong>trols, there is no legal basis by which to seize themthat could provide the crucial formal justificati<strong>on</strong>.Further, most ec<strong>on</strong>omic studies suggest high efficiencycosts and limited envir<strong>on</strong>mental impact of log exportbans, for instance, although the c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> gains mayrise with insecure land tenure and when informal loggingroads are more central in the process of forest clearing(see for example Boscolo and Vincent 2000; Kishor etal. 2004; Richards 1995; and v<strong>on</strong> Amsberg 1998). At theleast, then, identifying the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s under which thesepolicies will help seems critical.1.4.1.3. EU’s FLEGT Acti<strong>on</strong> Plan. <strong>The</strong> EU has taken a bilateral,voluntary approach to such trade measures in theForest Law Enforcement, Governance, and Trade Acti<strong>on</strong>(FLEGT) begun in 2003. <strong>The</strong> initiative relies <strong>on</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>allaw in the country of origin to define illegality of timberand wood products. <strong>The</strong> FLEGT program calls foragreements between exporting and EU countries to helpexporting nati<strong>on</strong>s to regulate and track forest practicesand to ensure <strong>on</strong>ly licensed timber is imported intoEU markets. While Ghana is the first country to c<strong>on</strong>cludea trade agreement under the program, Ind<strong>on</strong>esia,Malaysia, Camero<strong>on</strong>, Liberia, and C<strong>on</strong>go are engaged informal negotiati<strong>on</strong>s, and Vietnam, Gab<strong>on</strong>, and CentralAfrican Republic have expressed interest in the program(EUROPA 2009).<strong>The</strong>se agreements are designed to ultimately “eliminateillegally-produced timber from partner countries’internati<strong>on</strong>al and domestic trade” (FLEGT). Producercountries adopt administrative legal and technical systemsto verify that timber is produced in accordancewith nati<strong>on</strong>al laws. <strong>The</strong> EU provides financing to meetthese goals through improved enforcement and instituti<strong>on</strong>building. <strong>The</strong>se Voluntary Partnership Agreementsoriginally cover solid wood products (logs, plywood,veneers, etc.) and may be extended to manufacturedgoods at the export-country’s discreti<strong>on</strong>. This programis intended to reinforce producer-country governmentreforms that aim to improve forest governance in orderto improve access to EU markets, raise revenue fromtaxes or duties, and, thus, be able to finance povertyreducti<strong>on</strong>and community-development programs.FLEGT’s effectiveness is not yet known since its implementati<strong>on</strong>is still in its early stage. Criticisms from civilsociety assert that voluntary bilateral agreements are lesseffective than are legally binding c<strong>on</strong>trols up<strong>on</strong> timberimports, or regi<strong>on</strong>-wide enforcement protocols. HoweverFLEGT—especially in its focus up<strong>on</strong> deforestati<strong>on</strong>drivers, data collecti<strong>on</strong>, and law enforcement—mayinform the development of <strong>REDD</strong> approaches with voluntaryand legally binding systems, including for thebuilding of infrastructure and political intuiti<strong>on</strong>s for a<strong>REDD</strong> framework (Saunders et al.).1.4.1.4. United States’ Lacey Act and amendments. M<strong>on</strong>itoringtrade and imposing liability for illegal woodproducts in the supply chain may well effectively guidedemand. Designed properly, such restricti<strong>on</strong>s couldempower governments to stop illegal timber from slippinginto legal commerce and thereby dissuade the privatesector from indiscriminately sourcing its raw materials.<strong>The</strong> Lacey Act, which is am<strong>on</strong>g the oldest and mostsweeping of U.S. c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> laws, is a domestic tradeprovisi<strong>on</strong> with precisely such aims. Originally targetingtrade in endangered species, now it may diminishdemand for illegal timber.Nicholas Institute21


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiatives<strong>The</strong> Lacey Act was amended in 2008 to extend its reachto products derived from plants illegally harvestedwithin or outside the United States (including timber)and those manufactured outside of their country of origin(c<strong>on</strong>sider for example growing producti<strong>on</strong> of furniturein China based, it is believed, <strong>on</strong> illegal timbersupplies). This ban applies to most goods c<strong>on</strong>tainingwood products, such as furniture. Importers are nowrequired to declare country of origin, quantity, and plantspecies of their products. Violati<strong>on</strong>s carry civil or criminalpenalties based <strong>on</strong> a defendant’s knowledge of thelaw (USDA 2009). This casts an unprecedented wide netover illegal sourcing of timber and plants, and while <strong>on</strong>ecan imagine it being hampered by forgery and a lack ofdocumentati<strong>on</strong>, cases are being brought. Though it wasinitially intended to be fully enacted by 2008, the LaceyAct permitted extensi<strong>on</strong>s to give private firms—manufacturers,importers, and resellers—time to adjust procurementpractices and examine supply chains to screenout illegal wood products.Criticisms have focused <strong>on</strong> the cost and complicati<strong>on</strong>sof screening such supply chains. Yet that very focus <strong>on</strong>its costs itself suggests the potential for binding impact.<strong>The</strong> law’s mandates gives government the power to trulyrestrict imports of illegal timber (as defined at source)and imposes a duty <strong>on</strong> the importer to undertake areas<strong>on</strong>able level of due diligence. This achieves severalthings (USDA 2009):• it injects transparency into the supply chain bytransferring the initial effort of eliminating illegalwood and plant products from overburdened governmentagencies to purchasers;• it enables enforcement to be m<strong>on</strong>itored andthereby safeguarded by civil society groups; and• it provides customs with a mechanism to seizeplant products harvested illegally in other countries,removing protecti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>ce provided by thenorms of internati<strong>on</strong>al commerce.While effects of this law are not yet known, it is believedto be increasing transparency of the supply chain forwood products in the private sector. Such standards needto be adopted c<strong>on</strong>sistently by both exporters and importersif any such policy’s full potential is to be realized.1.4.2. Looking Aheadsimply small lots for differentiated markets, and whenall timber is labeled with its origin by mandate, thenimpacts could be significant.Bilateral and unilateral instruments can complement <strong>on</strong>eanother, but enforcement is key to any success. FLEGTillustrates disadvantages of bilateral instruments: theslow pace of negotiati<strong>on</strong>s, questi<strong>on</strong>able legal standardsin certain nati<strong>on</strong>s, and inability to address illegal tradein countries that do not agree to partner. However, properlydesigned, FLEGT could help reform forest industries.<strong>The</strong> Lacey Act dem<strong>on</strong>strates the strength of lawsin importing nati<strong>on</strong>s to place the <strong>on</strong>us <strong>on</strong> private entitiesto manage supply chains. Using nati<strong>on</strong>al law allowsborder agencies to seize and enforce bans against illegalimports, creating a powerful disincentive for producers.<strong>The</strong>se tools do not, however, directly address failingsal<strong>on</strong>g dimensi<strong>on</strong>s of interest within exporting countries’wood and forestry industries. Private-sector andcivil-society informati<strong>on</strong>-based campaigns can providecomplementary pressures that tip ec<strong>on</strong>omic incentivestoward sustainable management of forests. Other tradepolicies proposed by civil society could further diminishillegal timber trade and, presumably, illegal deforestati<strong>on</strong>:mandatory licensing of all timber exports; listingof unverified wood as “unknown source”; preventingendorsement of ineffective certificati<strong>on</strong>; third-partyverificati<strong>on</strong> of FLEG-like systems; and licensing to coverthe whole chain of wood processing. Yet despite recentprogress, including agreements between tropical forestnati<strong>on</strong>s and the U.S., Japan, and Australia—i.e., the largestdeveloped-country markets for tropical wood products—asingle systematic approach to deal with thesemarkets-and-incentives issues has not emerged.Many approaches applied in c<strong>on</strong>cert may have greatersuccess, since coerci<strong>on</strong> (law) and persuasi<strong>on</strong> (campaigns)appear to be complementary. In forested countrieswith large enough domestic demand (e.g., in thecase of Brazil, c<strong>on</strong>sider southern states’ purchases of beeffrom the Amaz<strong>on</strong>), such ideas even could be appliedpurely internally. Extensive analysis of their effectivenessis not yet available. However, assessments suggest significanteffects and potential for broader impact if appliedam<strong>on</strong>g more trading partners and markets. <strong>REDD</strong> presentsanother case for coordinated acti<strong>on</strong> (Daviet 2009).Market-mediated mechanisms to guide demand canlimit trade in illegal goods, but impacts will dependheavily <strong>on</strong> their scope and <strong>on</strong> enforceable mechanismsagainst illegal or undesired goods. When all of a largebuyer’s purchases meet such standards, i.e., when it is notNicholas Institute22


2. Domestic Forest PoliciesVaried nati<strong>on</strong>al and subnati<strong>on</strong>al initiativeshave aimed to c<strong>on</strong>serve forests. <strong>The</strong>ir primaryaim—reducing deforestati<strong>on</strong> as well as forest degradati<strong>on</strong>—hastypically been <strong>on</strong>ly partially achieved, due tolimitati<strong>on</strong>s in how key drivers of forest loss were (or werenot) addressed. For protected areas and ecoservices payments,being located where the threat of deforestati<strong>on</strong> isrelatively low has limited deforestati<strong>on</strong> impact, thoughimpacts <strong>on</strong> forest degradati<strong>on</strong> must also be c<strong>on</strong>sidered.C<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s by their nature should manage clearingpressures, yet many details of such c<strong>on</strong>tracts (much asfor ecopayments c<strong>on</strong>tracts) are critical if the local landuseincentives are really to shift. Finally, while decentralizati<strong>on</strong>does not automatically address these issues, ifincentives are well aligned then, in some situati<strong>on</strong>s, localdecisi<strong>on</strong>s could generate <strong>REDD</strong> while improving welfare.2.1. Protected AreasProtected areas are the most comm<strong>on</strong> explicit forestc<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> policy, now covering ~12% of the Earth’sland surface, and they have increased in area substantiallyover the past two decades. As they require m<strong>on</strong>ey,and other resources, an important questi<strong>on</strong> is whetherthey “work.” As they tend to be <strong>on</strong> land with relativelylow threat of deforestati<strong>on</strong>, though, protected areas maychange deforestati<strong>on</strong> less than expected relative to theoutcomes without a c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> policy. In particular,less deforestati<strong>on</strong> has been avoided by protected areasthan typically is assumed (see recent study of Costa Rica,the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>, Mexico, and all protected areasglobally).Better data could improve the limited evidence c<strong>on</strong>cerningpotentially higher impacts <strong>on</strong> forest degradati<strong>on</strong>.In fact, even for deforestati<strong>on</strong>, the recent studies showimpacts vary c<strong>on</strong>siderably across the landscape. Wheredeforestati<strong>on</strong> threats are relatively high and still theenforcement is sufficiently str<strong>on</strong>g, there can be significantavoided deforestati<strong>on</strong>, such as relatively big impactsof Chico Mendes Extractive Reserve in the BrazilianAmaz<strong>on</strong> nearby the Interoceanic Highway.Protecti<strong>on</strong> is established for many reas<strong>on</strong>s and protectedareas have varied land-use strictures. Many have beenfocused <strong>on</strong> where specific ecological services like speciesor carb<strong>on</strong> are most intensely provided. Other protecti<strong>on</strong>,and other analyses of its impact, have different foci suchas ec<strong>on</strong>omic opportunities afforded to or taken frompeople nearby (Sims 2009). <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> locals, includingaccess to n<strong>on</strong>timber forest products, can be critical forthe political and distributi<strong>on</strong>al comp<strong>on</strong>ents of <strong>REDD</strong>.We focus <strong>on</strong> deforestati<strong>on</strong> (drawing <strong>on</strong> Joppa and Pfaff2010a’s review).Because the reas<strong>on</strong> why protecti<strong>on</strong> can prevent deforestati<strong>on</strong>is comm<strong>on</strong> knowledge, we focus <strong>on</strong> the reas<strong>on</strong>why it may not. C<strong>on</strong>sider a completely forested protectedarea. It may not be achieving anything in deforestati<strong>on</strong>avoidance if the lands inside would be forestedanyway, without the formal protecti<strong>on</strong>. If land is steeplysloped, e.g., this may discourage deforestati<strong>on</strong> for crops(although perhaps not logging, as opposed to deforestati<strong>on</strong>,which serves as a reminder that degradati<strong>on</strong>impacts can be higher).In fact, globally, nati<strong>on</strong>al protected-area networks areoften unrepresentative of nati<strong>on</strong>al lands (Joppa andPfaff 2009). On dimensi<strong>on</strong>s relevant for deforestati<strong>on</strong>(in particular for agriculture), protected sites differ fromall unprotected lands and even lands directly aroundprotected areas. <strong>The</strong> former may not be surprising, ashousehold and agency choices suggest why pressuresmay generate n<strong>on</strong>random locati<strong>on</strong>s for protecti<strong>on</strong>. <strong>The</strong>latter comparis<strong>on</strong> is perhaps more surprising and, further,it is relevant to past efforts to evaluate impacts ofprotecti<strong>on</strong> (see Joppa and Pfaff 2010a) that now we seeeasily can overestimate avoided deforestati<strong>on</strong> (Joppa andPfaff 2010b). 102.1.1. Case Evidence2.1.1.1. Initial efforts. Protecti<strong>on</strong>’s impacts <strong>on</strong> deforestati<strong>on</strong>have l<strong>on</strong>g been evaluated (with less attenti<strong>on</strong> toforest degradati<strong>on</strong>), but the methods used have varied.Some informal evaluati<strong>on</strong>s involve <strong>on</strong>ly that currentlyforest is standing, e.g., Costa Rica’s protected areas area success as they are forested. Fuller et al. (2004), forinstance, say protecti<strong>on</strong> is not viable in Kalimantangiven the c<strong>on</strong>siderable deforestati<strong>on</strong> during 1996–2002.Yet c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s based solely up<strong>on</strong> the current forest arehighly problematic. To discern policy impact, we comparewhat occurred in an area to what would have happenedwithout protecti<strong>on</strong> and the latter must be inferred.Several approaches have been tried.10 C<strong>on</strong>sider this example of n<strong>on</strong>random locati<strong>on</strong> following local differences inland characteristics. Egm<strong>on</strong>t Nati<strong>on</strong>al Park in New Zealand c<strong>on</strong>tains a large volcanicc<strong>on</strong>e but stops at the c<strong>on</strong>e’s edge. Thus the elevati<strong>on</strong> in a buffer is markedlydifferent from inside the protected area. More generally, if there are thresholds orboundaries in natural landscapes, those who create the protected areas are likelyto be aware of them and might well choose to establish the protecti<strong>on</strong> al<strong>on</strong>g thosevery lines.Nicholas Institute23


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesOne might compare protected-area outcomes withdeforestati<strong>on</strong> in all of the unprotected areas. Gaveau etal. (2007) compare 30-year clearing of unprotected areaswith lower clearing within protecti<strong>on</strong>. Similar comparis<strong>on</strong>sare in Messina et al. (2006) for Ecuador’s Amaz<strong>on</strong>,Sánchez-Azofeifa et al. (1999) for Sarapiqui within CostaRica, and DeFries et al. (2005) for the globe.More comm<strong>on</strong>ly, analysts compare protected-area outcomesto the outcomes in “spatial buffers,” i.e., in areasimmediately surrounding the protected areas, in aneffort to compare similar lands. Bruner et al. (2001) analyzesthe deforestati<strong>on</strong> in and around 93 protected areasacross 22 tropical countries using survey data. Vina et al.(2007) update to 2001 a Wool<strong>on</strong>g study (Liu et al. 2001).Across the entire period from 1965 <strong>on</strong>, they found habitatlosses ~17% lower inside the reserve than in the buffer.Sader et al. (2001) compare the northern GuatemalanMaya Biosphere reserve (GMBR) with a buffer in fourtime periods, always finding higher clearing in the bufferz<strong>on</strong>e. Kinnaird et al. 2003 assessed deforestati<strong>on</strong> aroundBukit Barisan Selatan Nati<strong>on</strong>al Park <strong>on</strong> the Ind<strong>on</strong>esianisland of Sumatra (see Gaveau et al. 2007 above). From1985 to 1999, forest cover fell from 80% to 52% inside thepark, and from 15% to 1.6% in a 10km buffer around thepark. Many comparis<strong>on</strong>s like this find less deforestati<strong>on</strong>within protected areas then claim an impact.2.1.1.2. “Apples-to-apples.” Yet the characteristics of protectedlands often differ not <strong>on</strong>ly from the entire set ofunprotected areas but also from spatial buffers comm<strong>on</strong>lyassumed to be similar. “Matching” analyses canaddress such differences in deforestati<strong>on</strong>-relevant landcharacteristics by c<strong>on</strong>structing “apples to apples” comparis<strong>on</strong>s.<strong>The</strong>y use measurements of land characteristicsto select the most similar unprotected locati<strong>on</strong>s forcomparis<strong>on</strong>. Only recently has matching been applied toprotected areas, starting with Costa Rica (more below).Efforts are <strong>on</strong>going for the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong> (see Pfaffand Robalino 2009), the regi<strong>on</strong> around the InterOceanicHighway including Chico Mendes Extractive Reserve(Delgado et al. 2008), Mexico (Zepeda et al. 2010), andthe world using a data set that trades off detail for evaluati<strong>on</strong>of a huge set of countries (Joppa and Pfaff 2010b).Andam et al. (2008) estimate how much deforestati<strong>on</strong>was avoided within Costa Rica from 1960 to 1997 inover 150 protected areas. Costa Rica had high deforestati<strong>on</strong>during the 1960s and 1970s. <strong>The</strong>ir “matching”greatly increased the similarity to the protected areasof the unprotected areas selected for comparis<strong>on</strong>. <strong>The</strong>irapples-to-apples comparis<strong>on</strong> finds that ~11% of pixelsprotected would have been deforested without protecti<strong>on</strong>.Traditi<strong>on</strong>al analysis using the same data showsthat comparing to all unprotected land estimates 44%avoided deforestati<strong>on</strong> while comparing to a 10km spatialbuffer z<strong>on</strong>e corrects very little of this overestimate, yieldingan estimate of 38%.Building up<strong>on</strong> that to provide future policy guidancePfaff, Robalino et al. (2009) rec<strong>on</strong>sider Costa Rica’s protectedareas for 1986–1997. <strong>The</strong>y c<strong>on</strong>firm the Andam etal. (2008) story (with under 3% avoided deforestati<strong>on</strong>versus traditi<strong>on</strong>al estimates of 9%) and then focus <strong>on</strong>variati<strong>on</strong>s in impact. Relevant for future <strong>REDD</strong> investments,they find that some protected areas have far moreimpact <strong>on</strong> deforestati<strong>on</strong> than do others. For instance,within 85km of the capital of San Jose the avoided deforestati<strong>on</strong>was about 3%. Further away it was around 1%.Within 6km of a nati<strong>on</strong>al road, 5% of forest was c<strong>on</strong>servedwhile further away the impact was about zero.Finally, slope was critical. For flatter land they estimate14% avoidance, while <strong>on</strong> steeper land the impact wasclose to zero.2.1.2. Looking AheadProtected areas do avoid some deforestati<strong>on</strong> but muchless than previously has been assumed. It is worthemphasizing that this does not imply criticism of existingprotected areas’ locati<strong>on</strong>s or their management. Suchresource allocati<strong>on</strong> decisi<strong>on</strong>s are driven by any numberof motivati<strong>on</strong>s, and further we note that evidencec<strong>on</strong>cerning their impacts <strong>on</strong> forest degradati<strong>on</strong> is quitelimited.Yet this perspective is important for guiding futureinvestment. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> vary across a landscape. Deforestati<strong>on</strong>impact is likely to be lower <strong>on</strong> high slopes and landfarther from roads and cities (noting that where developmentmay arrive, l<strong>on</strong>g-run impacts may be higher thanthe short run). As global <strong>REDD</strong> payments are likely tobe based <strong>on</strong> impacts, integrating past motivati<strong>on</strong>s withearning payments suggests that, given all other c<strong>on</strong>straints,planners could target higher impact.2.2. EcopaymentsPayments for ecosystems services such as water quality,species habitat, or carb<strong>on</strong> storage could reward landownersfor limiting the uses of their lands to c<strong>on</strong>serveecosystems such as forests. Yet most proposed programsare voluntary. Landowners may volunteer their least productiveland and then be paid to retain forest that mightwell have remained without a financial reward.During the initial period of Costa Rica’s pi<strong>on</strong>eering program,which has inspired so many others, <strong>on</strong> averageNicholas Institute24


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativesdeforestati<strong>on</strong> threat was low and the payments were nottargeted at threat and thus the forests receiving paymentwould largely have remained standing without payments.However, as for protected areas, looking aheadplanners could explicitly aim payments at forest facingthreats. Costa Rica’s “learning laboratory for the world”also c<strong>on</strong>firms that the details of program design can becritical. Even after the program was already in place, theevoluti<strong>on</strong> over time and space in how the payments wereallocated affected the bias towards low threat and thuspayment impact.Here, as for protected areas, it is comm<strong>on</strong> knowledgewhy ecosystem services payments might prevent deforestati<strong>on</strong>so we focus <strong>on</strong> why they might not work. Whenpayment allocati<strong>on</strong> drives of agency decisi<strong>on</strong>s, the forcesleading protected areas to be biased to lower deforestati<strong>on</strong>threats apply to payments too. And as noted, whenlandowners choose to participate, given their detailedknowledge of their own lands they can pick out parcelswith poor soil quality or slopes to offer to the paymentsprogram. Those might remain forested even withoutpayments, such that payment impacts could be low.Evaluating impacts correctly requires comparing toother similar parcels.Landowner choice raises other issues too. One large relevantgroup is households in subsistence communitieswho grow crops for their own use and also collect n<strong>on</strong>timberforest products from unprotected open-accessforest and/or locally protected community forests (Sillset al. 2003). <strong>The</strong> most valuable forest products vary byregi<strong>on</strong> and forest type, with fuelwood more predominantin arid Asia and Africa (see Arnold et al. 2006, Hyde andAmacher 2001, and Sills et al. 2003).For these landowners, if <strong>REDD</strong> policies such as paymentsyield higher-quality or more extensive foreststocks to which households have access, householdsmay be better off. <strong>The</strong>se benefits can be <strong>on</strong> the orderof several m<strong>on</strong>ths of agricultural returns (Kohlin andAmacher 2005; Kohlin and Parks 2001) including viareduced collecti<strong>on</strong> times (Cooke 1998; Cooke et al. 2008;MacD<strong>on</strong>ald et al. 2001; Arnold et al. 2006). Under thissort of scenario, <strong>REDD</strong> can bring both climate changemitigati<strong>on</strong> and adaptati<strong>on</strong> benefits, e.g., a form of naturalinsurance (Pattanayak and Sills 2001).Yet if <strong>REDD</strong> policies largely benefit private forest stocksinstead, the additi<strong>on</strong>al rent may lead to higher enforcementin, i.e., exclusi<strong>on</strong> from, private forested areas.This may not <strong>on</strong>ly decrease the welfare of subsistencehouseholds but also shift their collecti<strong>on</strong> activity to moredegraded forests (Arnold et al. 2006; Cooke St. Claire etal. 2001; Vermeulen 2001). This dynamic could also berelevant if official protected areas (see 2.1 above) are betterenforced due to <strong>REDD</strong> payments.Given these distinct possibilities, farmers could beinvolved in policy design. Arnold et al. (2006) find in areview that transfer of local wood fuel reserves to communitiescan raise access to wood as well as revenuesgovernments collect through taxes and royalties inreturn for the guarantee of property rights (see 2.4 <strong>on</strong>decentralizati<strong>on</strong>). Yet at least for fuelwood, the transacti<strong>on</strong>scosts here may be high (Hofstad 1997). Still, wenote the possibility of “participatory payments schemes.”2.2.1. Case Evidence2.2.1.1. Initial efforts. As summarized in Sills et al. (forthcoming),some early studies of pi<strong>on</strong>eering Costa RicanPSA (Programa de Servicios Ambientales) paymentsfind more forest and less agriculture <strong>on</strong> fincas (essentiallyfarms) that receive payments. Yet the paymentsprogramparticipants differ from the n<strong>on</strong>participantsin terms of characteristics that affect land use (Ortiz etal. 2003; Miranda et al. 2003; Zbinden and Lee 2005).For instance, landowners can <strong>on</strong>ly obtain PSA payments<strong>on</strong> fincas for which they can establish clear ownership,while others are more likely to clear forest just to establishsuch property rights. Thus clearing may be lower <strong>on</strong>PSA fincas for reas<strong>on</strong>s unrelated to PSA.Studies also compare forest cover in a given finca beforeand after the establishment of the PSA. A teleph<strong>on</strong>e surveyof 100 PSA landowners across Costa Rica found 43%of forest receiving payments already was protected while36% was used for grazing before the c<strong>on</strong>tract (Ortiz et al.2003). Yet even c<strong>on</strong>cerning the latter significant number,rising forest cover <strong>on</strong> PSA fincas does not necessarilymean that the increase is due to PSA. Forest covercould be already increasing due to shifts in other factors(see Brockett and Gottfried 2002; de Camino et al. 2000;Miranda et al. 2006; Sánchez-Azofeifa et al. 2007). Evaluati<strong>on</strong>sshould ideally c<strong>on</strong>trol for such time trends.A variati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> this approach to evaluating paymentimpacts is illustrated by Sierra and Russman (2006). <strong>The</strong>ystudy land use <strong>on</strong> recently enrolled properties (c<strong>on</strong>tractssigned in the last two years) to approximate what theland use <strong>on</strong> properties that had been enrolled for morethan five years would have been had there been no paymentsprogram. <strong>The</strong>y find the PSA participants in theOsa Peninsula with recent c<strong>on</strong>tracts have significantlymore land in agricultural producti<strong>on</strong> than do earlierparticipants. <strong>The</strong>y c<strong>on</strong>clude that payments allow landholdersto invest in off-farm enterprises and accelerateNicholas Institute25


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativesexit from agriculture. Yet such observati<strong>on</strong> is <strong>on</strong>ly validfor impact estimati<strong>on</strong> if the factors that determine whenlandowners enroll do not also influence land use.2.2.1.2. Program evaluati<strong>on</strong> and program evoluti<strong>on</strong>. Justas for protected areas, in order to better evaluate impactsof ecoservices payments it helps to c<strong>on</strong>trol explicitly forany observable differences in land and landowner characteristicsbetween the sites that are receiving paymentsand the sites that are not. Recent evaluati<strong>on</strong>s apply the“matching” (just as above for protected areas) and bothpropensity-score matching (Rosenbaum and Rubin1983) and covariate matching (Abadie and Imbens 2006)for results robust to these approaches.Pfaff, Robalino and Sanchez (2008) find PSA c<strong>on</strong>tractsduring the period 1997–2000 blocked deforestati<strong>on</strong> inunder 0.1%—i.e., less than 1 in 1000—of the parcelsenrolled. Most of those enrolled were unlikely to clearthe forest even absent any payment. This does not mean,of course, that payments in any country would havesuch low impact. Rather, it shows that impact depends<strong>on</strong> the socioec<strong>on</strong>omic setting driving deforestati<strong>on</strong>and, thus, simply having payments does not guaranteemuch impact. In Costa Rica, there were are other factorsalready reducing rates of deforestati<strong>on</strong> by the time thepayments were created, leaving little for payments to do.Arriagada (2008) notes, however, that payments couldstill lead to regenerati<strong>on</strong> of forest, e.g., motivated by thepossible future payment.Further, in a given socioec<strong>on</strong>omic setting much canevolve, including the design of the payments. Robalino,Pfaff et al. (2008) study the sec<strong>on</strong>d time period for CostaRican payments, 2000–2005, finding that about 0.4%(or closer to 1 in 250) of the enrolled parcels were savedfrom clearing. To first order, this is also very low-impact.On the other hand, it is over four times as high here.Thus it is worth understanding why impact shifted. Tostart, during 2000–2005 Costa Rica <strong>on</strong> net reforested butmore gross deforestati<strong>on</strong> occurred, i.e., more changesthat payments could prevent.Probably more important for policy less<strong>on</strong>s, though, isa shift noted in Robalino, Pfaff et al. (2008) away froma bias towards even lower than the (very low) averagethreat. This shift is said to have resulted from moretop-down allocati<strong>on</strong> of PSA, reducing the influence ofvolunteer landowners. On average, across the country,this reducti<strong>on</strong> in low-threat biases raised the impact ofpayments. Also suggesting the importance of programdesign and implementati<strong>on</strong>, differences in allocati<strong>on</strong>rules across the agency offices within Costa Rica alsoyielded greatly varied impact of payments.2.2.2. Looking AheadEcosystem services payments can indeed avoid deforestati<strong>on</strong>but any impact cannot be assumed. Even withoutany spillovers (such as from relocati<strong>on</strong> of pressure toparcels with would otherwise have been forested), it isclear payments sometimes have little impact. <strong>The</strong> idea ofshifting local incentives remains valid though attenti<strong>on</strong>to the details of program design is required for impact.Deforestati<strong>on</strong> impacts are likely to be lower when selecti<strong>on</strong>into the program is driven by choices by landownersto volunteer parcels. Yet as for protected areas, forvarious motivati<strong>on</strong>s agencies too may enroll lands thatface lower-than-average deforestati<strong>on</strong> threat, e.g., fartherfrom roads or cities and with higher slope or lower soilquality. In either case, shifting details can raise impact.2.3. C<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>sIn the large tropical forests of Africa and Asia, andincreasingly Latin America, logging is often practicedthrough private c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s in government-owned forests.Many are held by large foreign firms. With variati<strong>on</strong>by country c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s are often c<strong>on</strong>tracts between governmentowner and harvester, w<strong>on</strong> through a biddingprocess, that designate a volume or area to harvest insome time period. C<strong>on</strong>tracts cover small or large areasand can be short- or l<strong>on</strong>g-term (see Gray 2000). Firmswinning c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s pay fees, or “royalties,” for theirrights. Royalties are usually lump sum fees charged based<strong>on</strong> the area harvested or, instead, fees based <strong>on</strong> volumeor species removed. Royalty revenues can be significant.Poor c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong> design has encouraged forest degradati<strong>on</strong>and made illegal logging more pervasive andc<strong>on</strong>tributed to forest loss (Gray 2002). Good design inprinciple offers potential for <strong>REDD</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s haverecently specified envir<strong>on</strong>mentally sensitive methodssuch as the preservati<strong>on</strong> of certain species, minimumsize-classharvesting, reduced-impact logging, and othermethods to reduce envir<strong>on</strong>mental impact (Karsenty2008; Cerutti et al. 2008). However, poor design of thec<strong>on</strong>tracts (including in the royalty structures) is comm<strong>on</strong>and enforcement problems are rife even where relevantc<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong> laws have been reformed. As a result,governments fail to capture appropriate revenue, toprotect habitat, to exclude illegal loggers (Merry andAmacher 2005) and to enforce agreed harvest methods(Smith et al. 2003).Yet c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong> design remains relevant to <strong>REDD</strong>.Domestically, any government could reform its policies<strong>on</strong> timber harvesting c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s to try to reduceNicholas Institute26


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativesnet forest carb<strong>on</strong> emissi<strong>on</strong>s below a nati<strong>on</strong>al baseline,e.g., providing incentives and increasing enforcement ofreduced-impact logging and other best practices (Pertzet al. 2007). At a global scale, <strong>on</strong>e might c<strong>on</strong>ceptualizenew <strong>REDD</strong> policy as a market for carb<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>swith countries as c<strong>on</strong>tractors. That idea is c<strong>on</strong>sistentwith the high-profile cases of nati<strong>on</strong>al governmentsseeking internati<strong>on</strong>al bidders to support c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>of forest that otherwise would be managed underresource c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s (see, e.g., Ngoïla-Mintom in Camero<strong>on</strong>[Karsenty 2007], or Yasuní in Ecuador [Larrea andWarnars 2009]). In Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, many NGOs developing<strong>REDD</strong> projects for the voluntary market and as pilots forany future compliance market are establishing additi<strong>on</strong>ality,permanence, and legal rights to the carb<strong>on</strong> throughecosystem restorati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s that preempt timberor oil palm c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s (Madeira 2009; DepartemenKehutanan 2009).C<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s remain the most comm<strong>on</strong> form of legaltimber harvesting in developing countries. <strong>The</strong>y arecomm<strong>on</strong>ly found in the large tropical forests of centraland western Africa, but also in more arid countries withdeciduous forests such as Benin. Timber c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>sare comm<strong>on</strong> in Asia, especially Ind<strong>on</strong>esia and Malaysia,and they are becoming more comm<strong>on</strong> in Latin America.Brazil, for instance, has just agreed to open more than 70milli<strong>on</strong> hectares in the Amaz<strong>on</strong> for future harvest c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s.Many of the c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong> buyers are foreign loggingfirms that have enough capital resources to developthe type of management and harvesting plans that aretypically required. However, Malaysia and other countrieshave promulgated policies, such as log export bans(see discussi<strong>on</strong> in 1.4), to favor domestic bidders (Kishoret al. 2004).<strong>The</strong>re has been much debate within varied literaturesabout how to design c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s to ensure sustainableharvesting, reduce illegal logging incentives, and ensureadequate government rent capture. Topics include c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>c<strong>on</strong>tract stipulati<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>cerning harvesting andlogging methods, the structure of royalties and fees, andgovernment oversight and enforcement. All of them arerelevant for thinking about the future of such c<strong>on</strong>tractsunder <strong>REDD</strong>. Carb<strong>on</strong> payments could c<strong>on</strong>ceivably bestructured through some type of carb<strong>on</strong>-c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>sc<strong>on</strong>tracting system.<strong>The</strong> design of c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s under ideal circumstances hasbeen debated for many years, with several recommendati<strong>on</strong>sabout design, i.e., royalty rates, enforcement effort,c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong> size, and envir<strong>on</strong>mentally sensitive loggingeffort (Hyde and Sedjo 1992). A comm<strong>on</strong> claim is thatroyalties are not used effectively to capture governmentrevenues or to stem illegal logging.Illegal logging typically comes in three forms: toomuch removal (area or volume), the failure to declareharvested volumes, and failure to use c<strong>on</strong>tracted loggingmethods or to harvest <strong>on</strong>ly the designated species(Barr 2001; Richards 1999; Gray 2002; Hardner and Rice2000). High grading, or removal of <strong>on</strong>ly the best or highest-valuedtrees, is <strong>on</strong>e realizati<strong>on</strong> of this issue.A comm<strong>on</strong> idea is to raise royalty rates to increase governmentrent collecti<strong>on</strong> and also reduce excessive harvesting,thus lower logging impact (see Gray 2002; Vincent1990; Merry et al. 2002; Palmer 2003). Others havecalled for a shift to area-based lump sum royalties insteadof basing fees up<strong>on</strong> stated volume, which is often err<strong>on</strong>eouslydeclared by the harvester (Barr 2001; Richards1999; Gray 2002; Hardner and Rice 2000). Yet Boscoloand Vincent (2007) argue that even high area fees caninduce unsustainable harvesting behavior. Another comm<strong>on</strong>idea is to increase (very costly) state enforcementeffort in an attempt to catch and punish illegal harvest.Yet early c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s literature did not deal with illegallogging that undeniably exists. Formal studies of illegallogging incentives in public c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s include Boscoloand Vincent (2000), who analyze the impact of royalties<strong>on</strong> use of minimum site impact (i.e., envir<strong>on</strong>mentallysensitive) logging practices by loggers. Clarke et al.(1993) study the role of penalty schemes and optimaldynamic enforcement expenditures <strong>on</strong> open access forestexploitati<strong>on</strong>, while Walker and Smith (1993) modeln<strong>on</strong>compliance choice by loggers facing a particularc<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>tract.Amacher et al. (2007) examine reform in royalties thatcan reduce illegal logging in the form of harvestingbey<strong>on</strong>d c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s. <strong>The</strong>y show that the royalty reformneeded depends <strong>on</strong> harvesters’ risk preferences (correlatedwith firm size) and the type of penalties the governmentcould use for illegal logging of various forms.<strong>The</strong>y also find that higher “royalty regressi<strong>on</strong>” (i.e., lowermarginal royalties as volume increases) can raise reportingof harvest volumes and reduce cheating if a revenueneutralreform and other enforcement effort choices arejointly c<strong>on</strong>sidered. This idea seems robust, as Boscoloand Vincent (2007) find a similar result in a differentmodel.2.3.2. Looking AheadFor <strong>REDD</strong>, a message from this literature is that allinstruments (royalties, enforcement, and c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>Nicholas Institute27


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativesc<strong>on</strong>tract stipulati<strong>on</strong>s) must be designed together andnot thought of independently if the goal is to ensureadequate government rent capture, a high level of emissi<strong>on</strong>sreducti<strong>on</strong>s, and minimized illegal logging that canerode these emissi<strong>on</strong>s reducti<strong>on</strong>s. Yet the applicati<strong>on</strong>s ofsuch c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s thinking will differ across countries.<strong>The</strong> works cited establish that successful use of theseinstruments depends critically <strong>on</strong> the structure of governance,resources the state has for enforcement, andother problems that can undermine c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong> designsuch as corrupti<strong>on</strong>.Yet it remains the case that reform of timber c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>scould help reduce deforestati<strong>on</strong> and forest degradati<strong>on</strong>.Better design and enforcement could raise adopti<strong>on</strong>of reduced-impact logging and other best managementpractices that significantly enhance carb<strong>on</strong> storage(Pinard and Cropper 2000; www.raftprogram.org).Increased government revenue capture could be used fordebt relief (see 1.3 above). If c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s provide moreincome for the government, this can support the combatingof corrupti<strong>on</strong> and illegal logging <strong>on</strong> the fr<strong>on</strong>tier.<strong>The</strong>se activities may in fact be complementary, becauseif enforcement (e.g., for reduced impact) rises <strong>on</strong>ly insome areas, then broader enforcement may be requiredto combat potential “leakage”—or the displacement oflogging activity—toward more easily exploited areassuch as smallholder or village-based forests.In additi<strong>on</strong>, under a project-based approach to <strong>REDD</strong>,countries could just swap harvest c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s for carb<strong>on</strong>c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s, with <strong>REDD</strong> payments compensating for theexpected loss in rents from not harvesting. If all relevantlocal actors are adequately compensated, there could beseveral advantages for public goods producti<strong>on</strong> and evenclimate benefits in carb<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s.Finally, were such swaps to happen, we note that loweringtimber supply could also have important impacts<strong>on</strong> timber markets. It can increase prices and divertdemand, yielding leakage to forests outside c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>sincluding in neighboring countries (as is believed tohave resulted from China’s restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> timber harvest).On the other hand, with greater enforcement anda global <strong>REDD</strong> regime, higher timber prices could alsoprovide an incentive afforestati<strong>on</strong>/reforestati<strong>on</strong>.2.4. Decentralizati<strong>on</strong>Many of the world’s forests were <strong>on</strong>ce governed as comm<strong>on</strong>-propertyregimes (McKean 2002). In the developingworld, most of these traditi<strong>on</strong>al regimes were legallydisavowed when col<strong>on</strong>ial and then central state governmentsdeclared themselves owners of all forests. Inmost tropical countries, the majority of forests are stillowned by the state. This has left the milli<strong>on</strong>s who livein these forests with <strong>on</strong>ly usufruct or “use” rights to theforest and—at least in a legal sense—no rights to own, tomanage, or to block others’ exploitati<strong>on</strong> of the resourcesup<strong>on</strong> which their livelihoods depend. <strong>The</strong> persistenceof tropical deforestati<strong>on</strong> suggests that central state ownershipand management often has not addressed thesefacts at least in the sense of having sustainable forestmanagement and forest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>.Extensive areas of state-owned forests in the tropics arez<strong>on</strong>ed as timber or as agricultural c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s. Othersare z<strong>on</strong>ed as parks and others as public lands with nodesignated use. As the authority to enforce rests with astate entity whose presence is often minimal due to budgetsor corrupti<strong>on</strong>, open-access and the “tragedy of thecomm<strong>on</strong>s” frequently result. McKean 2002 states: “<strong>The</strong>transfer of property rights from traditi<strong>on</strong>al user groupsto others eliminates incentives for m<strong>on</strong>itoring andrestrained use, c<strong>on</strong>verts owner-protectors into poachers. . . ” <strong>The</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sequences have included illegal logging,clearing, and burning in many state-owned tropicalforests including in nati<strong>on</strong>al parks (Curran et al. 2004;Jenkins 2008).Yet over the past two decades, numerous central governmentshave devolved both forest ownership andmanagement resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities to local instituti<strong>on</strong>s. Asof 2001, at least 60 countries reported some decentralizati<strong>on</strong>reforms in natural resources (Agrawal 2001).Increasingly, this includes granting local communitiesproperty rights to forested lands (Sunderlin 2008). <strong>The</strong>stated objectives of these reforms have included all ofimproved efficiency, greater equity, and the effectivenessof forest management.Such decentralizati<strong>on</strong> has already taken many forms.That includes the devoluti<strong>on</strong> of property rights or managementauthority to a community, e.g., legally recognizinga traditi<strong>on</strong>al comm<strong>on</strong>-property regime (e.g., communityforests in Camero<strong>on</strong> and India). It also includesthe transfer of forest management resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities tostate or to local governments (i.e., enforcing rules andcollecting revenues). 1111 Some distinguish these two types of reforms, categorizing power transfersto local-level authorities within government as “decentralizati<strong>on</strong>” and transfersto local-level authorities outside of government (such as communities) as“devoluti<strong>on</strong>.” However, such distincti<strong>on</strong>s may not always work, since in somecases community-level instituti<strong>on</strong>s may operate as a form of local government(as in Tanzania) or in some cases, both types of power transfers occur at the sametime (as in Bolivia). Following Anne Lars<strong>on</strong>’s (2004) approach, we term all suchreforms as decentralizati<strong>on</strong>.Nicholas Institute28


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesAs to why such decentralizati<strong>on</strong> might help to reduceforest loss, in particular by reducing degradati<strong>on</strong>, whileindividual ownership and state ownership were l<strong>on</strong>g theopti<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>sidered, from the late 1980s increasing interestwas paid to cases where property rights and managementresp<strong>on</strong>sibilities were held by groups of forestusers and effective local instituti<strong>on</strong>s were developed(Ostrom 1990). Some suggest that comm<strong>on</strong>-propertyregimes even can be the most efficient way to managenatural resources that are (1) remote, emphasizing groupm<strong>on</strong>itoring and enforcement, or (2) biophysically moreproductive as a large unit versus as fragmented patches(McKean 2002). Both c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s can hold in tropicalforest regi<strong>on</strong>s. 12Other theories regarding decentralizati<strong>on</strong> posit thatbringing government “closer to the people” will induceparticipati<strong>on</strong> and increase the accountability of governmentinstituti<strong>on</strong>s (Lars<strong>on</strong> 2004). Local communities andgovernments may have better informati<strong>on</strong> about localc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s and preferences and thus make better decisi<strong>on</strong>sabout collective goods (Anderss<strong>on</strong> and Lehoucq2006). Ribot and Lars<strong>on</strong> argue that for decentralizati<strong>on</strong>to work it must be democratic in nature. Sufficient powersmust be transferred to instituti<strong>on</strong>s that are downwardlyaccountable to local populati<strong>on</strong>s (Ribot 2002;Ribot and Lars<strong>on</strong> 2005).2.4.1. Case EvidenceAssessment of decentralizati<strong>on</strong>’s impacts is limited.Despite many stories, empirical studies of impacts <strong>on</strong>forest cover and human welfare are few. Rigorous examinati<strong>on</strong>of pre-decentralizati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s or specificcharacteristics of reform are limited. Outcome measuresdiffer across the studies that exist. Some examine howcharacteristics of local instituti<strong>on</strong>s and decentralizati<strong>on</strong>reforms affect changes in forest cover (Alix-Garciaet al. 2004; Alix-Garcia 2007; Chhatre and Agrawal2008) while others examine just local wood extracti<strong>on</strong>(Edm<strong>on</strong>ds 2002) or local instituti<strong>on</strong>al effort (Anderss<strong>on</strong>et al. 2006) or human welfare (Cooper 2008; Jumbe andAngelsen 2006). Only a few studies compare decentralizedoutcomes with the impacts of centralized state management(Nepstad et al. 2006b and Somanathan et al.2009 <strong>on</strong> forest degradati<strong>on</strong> [not <strong>on</strong> deforestati<strong>on</strong>], notingthat this study also compared community efforts with12 However, Dietz et al. (2003) argue that comm<strong>on</strong>-property regimes aremost effective under a more limited set of c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s: (1) possible to m<strong>on</strong>itorthe resources and their use at low cost; (2) no more than moderate changes insocioec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, populati<strong>on</strong> growth, technology, and resource use; (3)high social capital (so that community members can trust each other, enforcerules, and achieve m<strong>on</strong>itoring at low costs); (4) possible to exclude outsiders atlow costs; and (5) users support m<strong>on</strong>itoring and enforcement of rules.open access). Only <strong>on</strong>e includes the relative efficiency orimplementati<strong>on</strong> cost (Somanathan et al. 2009).Further complicating assessment are incomplete powertransfers within the decentralizati<strong>on</strong> efforts to date.Some argue that evaluating impacts is premature sinceoften “decentralizati<strong>on</strong>” was in name <strong>on</strong>ly (Ribot 2002;Shacklet<strong>on</strong> et al. 2002). Ribot and Lars<strong>on</strong> (2005) say thatoften sufficient and secure powers have not been transferredto local instituti<strong>on</strong>s and that instituti<strong>on</strong>s are notdownwardly accountable. Even with baselines and metrics,the “underlying logic” of decentralizati<strong>on</strong> may notbe able to be well tested using current experiences. Nevertheless,we present some empirical and case literature.2.4.1.1. Decentralizati<strong>on</strong> can work. Indigenous territoriesand community-managed extractive reserves appear tohave blocked clearing, e.g., in the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>. 13Here, inhabitants possess secure and exclusive use rightsand thus the right to block outsiders from encroachment.Nepstad et al. (2006b) and Adeney et al. (2009)have found that indigenous reserves do as well as parksin blocking deforestati<strong>on</strong> and fire. Pfaff et al. (2010) findthat all of these areas reduced deforestati<strong>on</strong> less than isclaimed (see 2.1) but that indigenous areas fared betterthan state areas. Exclusi<strong>on</strong> of others occurs even in areasof intense pressure (Nepstad et al. 2006b).Forests under community management in Kuma<strong>on</strong>,India, have been sustainably managed for decades(Agrawal 2001). Some c<strong>on</strong>clude that Van Panchayats(community forest councils) are more effective in c<strong>on</strong>servingthan are state agencies (Somanathan et al. 2009).In Mexico, where most forests are held as comm<strong>on</strong>property, many communities sustainably manage forests(Alix-Garcia et al. 2004). Since Bolivia’s decentralizati<strong>on</strong>reforms in the 1990s, including recogniti<strong>on</strong> of22 milli<strong>on</strong> hectares of indigenous lands (3 milli<strong>on</strong> hectareshave been titled), improved forest management isreported (Pacheco 2005). In Nicaragua, where the BosawasReserve overlaps lands demarcated for indigenouspeoples it is better defended against encroachment anddeforestati<strong>on</strong> than are areas solely under state management(Stocks et al. 2007). In Nepal, which devolvedmanagement rights to communities in the 1970s, communitymanagement has d<strong>on</strong>e a better job of maintainingand increasing forest cover than state management(Nagendra 2007).13 More land is under management by indigenous communities (21%) thanis in protected areas (PAs) (14%) (Schwartzman and Zimmerman 2005). WhileBrazil’s 1988 c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> required the demarcati<strong>on</strong> of all indigenous lands by1993, the task might have g<strong>on</strong>e unfinished were it not for foreign d<strong>on</strong>ors and thePPG7. PPG7 also piloted participatory demarcati<strong>on</strong> with indigenous peoples,reducing demarcati<strong>on</strong> costs and likely increasing capacities of these communitiesto defend their territories (Fearnside 2005a).Nicholas Institute29


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesCases of community management increasing revenueand benefits for local populati<strong>on</strong>s have also been documented.Tanzania provides <strong>on</strong>e example. <strong>The</strong> 2002 ForestAct in Tanzania devolved timber licensing and revenuecollecti<strong>on</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities from the district to the village.Transparency and accountability have been increased byrequiring that village instituti<strong>on</strong>s document and publiclyshare all revenues and expenditures, yielding increasesin revenue collecti<strong>on</strong> and the financing of public services(Lund 2007).2.4.1.2. Decentralizati<strong>on</strong> is not a panacea. Yet decentralizati<strong>on</strong>can increase deforestati<strong>on</strong> and inequality, ifattenti<strong>on</strong> is not paid to instituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s and toec<strong>on</strong>omic incentives. If the short-term ec<strong>on</strong>omic incentivesfor c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> are not higher than those fromcommodities, e.g., then we may well expect that deforestati<strong>on</strong>will c<strong>on</strong>tinue.Traditi<strong>on</strong>al communities are not inherently focused <strong>on</strong>c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> al<strong>on</strong>e. <strong>The</strong>y and other locals may well aimto maximize ec<strong>on</strong>omic returns from the forests, Wherec<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> incentives are lacking, deforestati<strong>on</strong> mayrise under local c<strong>on</strong>trol. C<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> of forests to agriculturehas been observed in reserves in Mato Grosso(Fearnside 2005b) as have logging and forest degradati<strong>on</strong>(Asner et al. 2005).Rapid and destructive logging has also plagued somecommunity forests in Camero<strong>on</strong> (Oy<strong>on</strong>o 2005). It hasbeen speculated that the management rights granted tothese communities are not secure (e.g., can be revokedby the state), so residents may wish to accrue forest profitswhile they can (Oy<strong>on</strong>o 2004). Another factor may bea lack of downwardly accountability, if village elites promotedlogging to derive pers<strong>on</strong>al gain at the expense ofthe community’s welfare (Oy<strong>on</strong>o et al. 2003; Ribot 2002;Lars<strong>on</strong> and Ribot 2007).In Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, authority for granting timber and forestc<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> licenses and collecting some revenues wasrapidly decentralized to the district level during 1999-2002, followed by some re-centralizati<strong>on</strong>. This clearlydid not slow degradati<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> of forests (Barret al. 2006; Capistrano 2008; Dahal and Adhikari 2008).By many accounts, despite a temporary increase in cashincome, local communities have benefitted little. Whilelocals may be granted timber licenses, they lack the capitalto do logging and usually c<strong>on</strong>tract with large loggingcompanies (Resosudarmo 2004). Lacking secure propertyrights and access to fair judicial systems, and thestates’ inability or unwillingness to enforce these c<strong>on</strong>tracts,communities have been vulnerable to exploitati<strong>on</strong>(Engel and Palmer 2008). This has also led to disputeover property rights, with local elites often seeking totake advantage. As summarized by Barr (2006: 130),“although since decentralizati<strong>on</strong>, local communities’right to obtain a share in benefits is no l<strong>on</strong>ger disputed,their relatively weak legal bargaining power has allowedmore powerful parties to reap more.”Findings are mixed regarding effects of the size of theforest area and group of users. With data from the Internati<strong>on</strong>alForestry Resources and Instituti<strong>on</strong>s communityforest program across nine countries, Chhatre andAgrawal (2008) find degradati<strong>on</strong> is more likely in largerareas and say it may be harder to m<strong>on</strong>itor larger tracts.Yet with the same dataset, the same authors later assertthat larger community forests store more carb<strong>on</strong> andyield greater livelihood benefits (firewood, fodder, greenbiomass, c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> wood) to users (Chhatre andAgrawal 2009). Nagendra 2007 studies Nepal, arguingdecentralizati<strong>on</strong> may be most effective at intermediategroup sizes: “When the number of users is too few relativeto the total forest area, forest planting, maintenance,m<strong>on</strong>itoring, and other critical tasks cannot be carriedout effectively. When the number of users increasesbey<strong>on</strong>d a point, however, coordinati<strong>on</strong> becomes difficultand cooperati<strong>on</strong> tends to break down, making thetask of forest protecti<strong>on</strong> even more difficult.” Nagendrafocuses <strong>on</strong> reforestati<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s such as the abovecould depend up<strong>on</strong> the issue at hand, e.g., externallydrivendeforestati<strong>on</strong>, internally-driven degradati<strong>on</strong>, orinternally-driven restorati<strong>on</strong>.2.4.2. Looking AheadDecentralizati<strong>on</strong> may turn out to be an effective policytool for reducing forest degradati<strong>on</strong>. Yet for it to workrequires attenti<strong>on</strong> to local instituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s. First,local instituti<strong>on</strong>s require secure rights to own or managethe forest. In the c<strong>on</strong>text of <strong>REDD</strong>, clear rights to enterinto forest carb<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tracts in particular may be necessary.Sec<strong>on</strong>d, local instituti<strong>on</strong>s need financial incentivesfor c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>, such as the prospect of carb<strong>on</strong> payments.Third, local instituti<strong>on</strong>s need to be transparentand downwardly accountable to the local populati<strong>on</strong>s to,in turn, face and receive financial incentives for c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>(carb<strong>on</strong> payments, better social services or otherbenefits). Fourth, if local populati<strong>on</strong>s have property andcomplementary rights (e.g., to citizenship, participati<strong>on</strong>,and redress) then local instituti<strong>on</strong>s may be more likelyto be downwardly accountable. Finally, local instituti<strong>on</strong>srequire the support of central state authorities formanaging their lands, e.g., technical assistance, capacity,enforcement of c<strong>on</strong>tracts, and more generally the abilityto administer justice given c<strong>on</strong>flict am<strong>on</strong>g local instituti<strong>on</strong>s(Lars<strong>on</strong> 2004).Nicholas Institute30


3. Other Domestic PoliciesAdjusting other domestic policies with significanteffects up<strong>on</strong> deforestati<strong>on</strong> may be as importantfor <strong>REDD</strong> as optimizing c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> with less<strong>on</strong>s frompast forest-focused domestic policies. 14 Yet little experimentati<strong>on</strong>of this type has occurred, to our knowledge.Below we describe how these development policies affectdeforestati<strong>on</strong> and suggest that such policies could beadjusted.3.1. Infrastructure PoliciesAccess and transport costs are key determinants of agricultureas well as of logging. Investments in new roadsraise access, lower transport cost, and often lead to bothmore ec<strong>on</strong>omic output and increased deforestati<strong>on</strong>.Critically though, new road impacts vary across space.Specifically, new road investments appear to increasedeforestati<strong>on</strong> less when they are made in already developedareas, with prior roads and deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Thustotal forest impact is affected by network design (andan analogous point should apply to energy pipelines). Inadditi<strong>on</strong>, the government of Acre, an Amaz<strong>on</strong>ian statein Brazil, claims that deforestati<strong>on</strong> can be lower if publicactors sequence or integrate road c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> withother policies that clarify tenure and provide services inorder to raise the quality of life while preserving naturalwealth. Another integrati<strong>on</strong> example could be a bufferof parks around roads, imitating how Chico MendesExtractive Reserve has functi<strong>on</strong>ed.Since agriculture is the primary land use to which forestis c<strong>on</strong>verted, note that a model of such choices mightinclude owners maximizing profits (or goals includingprofits) in deciding am<strong>on</strong>g alternative land uses.Improved access, i.e., feasibility of transport and itscost, should increase net revenues from outputs andlower costs of inputs from labor to fertilizers. How thisaffects the profits from clearing versus from forest willdrive land use. New roads could support more forest inprinciple but in many situati<strong>on</strong>s the net benefits of suchinvestments are greater given clearing. On average acrossvaried settings, then, road investments are expected toincrease deforestati<strong>on</strong>.To c<strong>on</strong>sider future potential <strong>REDD</strong> policies, though,we may go bey<strong>on</strong>d points about averages. Below, forinstance, we focus <strong>on</strong> the heterogeneity in impact thatcreates the potential for shifts in road policy to generate<strong>REDD</strong>. If the impact of a new road varies as a functi<strong>on</strong>of the setting into which the investment goes, then where<strong>on</strong>e sites the investments affects total deforestati<strong>on</strong>.3.1.1. Case Evidence3.1.1.1. Transport cost matters. That changes in transportinfrastructure affect deforestati<strong>on</strong> is empirically supported.One way to see this is to study the agents whodecide whether to clear an area (see, e.g., Sills and Caviglia-Harris2008). Regressi<strong>on</strong>s at this scale require datafrom farm households with questi<strong>on</strong>s about the extentof deforestati<strong>on</strong> (number of hectares or percent of landholding)as well as about many factors that influence it.Current research focuses <strong>on</strong> linking such survey datawith measures of deforestati<strong>on</strong> from remote sensing (seeFox et al. 2003; Caviglia-Harris et al. 2009). Results ofsuch analyses generally show improved access to roadsand market centers raises deforestati<strong>on</strong>.At larger scales as well, the evidence supports this c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> the impact of transport cost. Recently, moreec<strong>on</strong>omists study deforestati<strong>on</strong> across regi<strong>on</strong>s withina country by combining census data with increasinglyaccessible remote sensing data (Pfaff 1999 is an earlyexample). Where data are available, <strong>on</strong>e can see thathigher agricultural prices are generally found to be associatedwith more deforestati<strong>on</strong> (see Angelsen 1999, e.g.,<strong>on</strong> indices of agricultural output prices in Tanzania).Biophysical factors (soil quality, slope, rainfall) can bekey c<strong>on</strong>straints.C<strong>on</strong>trolling for such factors, investments that raisetransport access or lower its cost, as proxied by proximityto roads, are correlated with higher deforestati<strong>on</strong>.Chomitz and Thomas (2003) find distance to roads andrainfall negatively correlated with deforestati<strong>on</strong> in BrazilianAmaz<strong>on</strong>ia. 15 For Thailand, Cropper et al. (2001)find biophysical factors have the str<strong>on</strong>gest correlati<strong>on</strong>with deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Yet roads and populati<strong>on</strong> density areclearly positively related to deforestati<strong>on</strong>.Stepping back even further, for broader descriptive facts,over two-thirds of Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong> deforestati<strong>on</strong> has14 V<strong>on</strong> Thünen’s (1966) useful simple framework emphasizes the importancefor land use choices of distances to market center, suggesting that (1) deforestati<strong>on</strong>can increase with improved access, (2) deforestati<strong>on</strong> increases with profitabilityof agriculture and lower profits in forest, and (3) increasing forest profitwould expand the “mining” of forest resources farther into the wilderness.15 Since as found in Pfaff (1999) roads in <strong>on</strong>e political unit could well affectclearing in neighbors, and in principle the sign of such an effect is ambiguous,Pfaff et al. (2007) looks at impacts of new roads <strong>on</strong> census tracts in the samecounty that do not receive road investments. Deforestati<strong>on</strong> increases in censustracts within 100km of the census tract receiving the new road.Nicholas Institute31


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativestaken place within 50km of major paved roads, resultingin the oft-noted “arc of deforestati<strong>on</strong>” in the southernAmaz<strong>on</strong> (Nepstad et al. 2001; Laurance et al. 2001;Chomitz and Thomas 2003). In this regi<strong>on</strong> (examinedfurther below), two major roads were inaugurated in theearly 1960s: the BR-010 c<strong>on</strong>necting Brasília (the nati<strong>on</strong>alcapital) to Belém (the capital of Pará) in the east; andalso the BR-364 c<strong>on</strong>necting Cuiabá (the capital of MatoGrosso) to Porto Velho (the capital of R<strong>on</strong>dônia) in thewest. <strong>The</strong>se are two of the areas with greatest clearing.3.1.1.2. Road impacts vary by locati<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>tinuing c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>of the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>, in the early 1970sthe Transamazônica/BR-230, which runs east to westacross the states of Pará and Amaz<strong>on</strong>as, and the BR-163,which runs south to north from Cuiabá (Mato Grosso) toSantarém (Pará), were c<strong>on</strong>structed but not paved. <strong>The</strong>irimpact is magnified by a network of over 300,000km ofunofficial logging tracks (Brandão and Souza 2006; Perzet al. 2007). Currently, the fr<strong>on</strong>tier with highest clearingrates is in the central Amaz<strong>on</strong>, al<strong>on</strong>g BR-163. Across thisenormous regi<strong>on</strong>, subregi<strong>on</strong>s vary a great deal.New roads’ impacts may vary c<strong>on</strong>siderably across spacetoo, as a functi<strong>on</strong> of key details of the setting in whichthey are located. 16 Andersen et al. (2002) study roadimpact as a functi<strong>on</strong> of prior clearing within a county.With about 250 county-level observati<strong>on</strong>s they assumethat higher prior deforestati<strong>on</strong> always raises or alwayslowers a new road’s forest impact. Am<strong>on</strong>g those opti<strong>on</strong>s,they find that where prior deforestati<strong>on</strong> is higher, theforest impact of a new road will be lower.Pfaff, Robalino and Herrera (2009) reexamine variati<strong>on</strong>in road investments’ impacts using much more precisepixel data. 17 <strong>The</strong>se permit the prior distance to the nearestroad as a more spatially precise proxy for prior development.Unlike the interacti<strong>on</strong> estimated in Andersen16 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> vary over time as well. Over time in the Amaz<strong>on</strong>, not <strong>on</strong>ly have700,000km² or about 17% of the forest in Brazil been c<strong>on</strong>verted to other landuses (INPE 2008), but also land-use dynamics c<strong>on</strong>tinue to shift. <strong>The</strong> processwas initiated by government to integrate the remote regi<strong>on</strong> with the rest of thecountry using roads, col<strong>on</strong>izati<strong>on</strong> projects, and agricultural subsidies (Mahar1989). Today deforestati<strong>on</strong> is largely driven by private investors seeking profits bysupplying global and domestic markets for timber, soybeans, and beef (Margulis2003; Nepstad et al. 2006; Lentini et al. 2005; Arima and Barreto 2005). <strong>The</strong>logging industry plays a critical role in opening new areas by building unofficialnew roads (Veríssimo et al. 2002; Brandão and Souza 2006; Perz et al. 2007). Yetgovernment also still c<strong>on</strong>tributes to deforestati<strong>on</strong> by investing in infrastructure,facilitating credit for agriculture, and recognizing and supporting new settlementsof small farmers in forested areas (Fearnside 2005c; Barreto et al. 2008).17 This advance in data permits c<strong>on</strong>siderably more precisi<strong>on</strong> even than withinthe work in Pfaff et al. (2006) and Pfaff et al. (2008), which went bey<strong>on</strong>d thecounty data using over 6,000 census tract observati<strong>on</strong>s that allow splitting thesample by prior clearing. Both analyses, as in Andersen et al. (2002), proxiedprior development using prior deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Across multiple periods, theseanalyses c<strong>on</strong>firm that new roads’ forest impacts vary with setting but do not findroad investments to ever lower deforestati<strong>on</strong>.et al. 2002, this also permits a test of a new predicti<strong>on</strong>of n<strong>on</strong>m<strong>on</strong>ot<strong>on</strong>ic effects of prior development up<strong>on</strong>new roads investments’ short-run forest impacts. Thus,with high prior development, new roads’ impacts canbe quite low and even insignificant (as in Andersen etal. 2002). However, impact does not rise uniformly asprior development falls. Instead, it is highest at an intermediatelevel of prior development, what <strong>on</strong>e might callthe edge of development where more can easily occur.Further out from development centers, where little priordevelopment has occurred, again impact of new roads isrelatively low, at least in the short run (and varied l<strong>on</strong>grundynamics could arise, from road aband<strong>on</strong>ment toenormous shifts over decades as new investments followprior <strong>on</strong>es).C<strong>on</strong>de and Pfaff (2008) show supporting pixel evidencefrom the Mayan forest (in Mexico, Belize, and Guatemala).<strong>The</strong> short-run impact of the new road investmentsfurther from prior roads is lower than the impactof new road investments closer to prior development(noting there is not enough data in areas of very highprior development to test that element of the n<strong>on</strong>m<strong>on</strong>ot<strong>on</strong>icityseen above). Further, it is clear that within themore remote areas, it is <strong>on</strong>ly the road investment andnot other characteristics that significantly shape spatialpaths of clearing. C<strong>on</strong>de et al. 2010’s examinati<strong>on</strong> ofroad impact up<strong>on</strong> jaguar habitat also reminds us thatlow short-run deforestati<strong>on</strong> impacts in the more remote,pristine areas could imply large additi<strong>on</strong>al impacts. Fragmentati<strong>on</strong>impacts are clearly much higher as a result ofmore remote new roads and can matter to species.Delgado et al. (2010) provide supporting pixel evidencefor areas of higher prior development and clearing,focusing <strong>on</strong> the Inter-Oceanic Highway c<strong>on</strong>necting thewestern Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong> with Peru, running al<strong>on</strong>g theborder of Brazil with Bolivia. <strong>The</strong> highway was establishedin unpaved form by 1989 and then the Braziliansecti<strong>on</strong> was paved during 2002–2004. <strong>The</strong> critical resultfor <strong>REDD</strong> is that distance from the highway is significantlynegatively associated with deforestati<strong>on</strong> during1989–2000, in all three countries, but it is not significantfor deforestati<strong>on</strong> during 2000-2007. While eliminatingthis transport corridor would surely slow clearing, thepaving did not shape local clearing given an alreadyestablished local pattern of development. Linking tothe results above, the existence of significant prior localdevelopment lessened new road impact.3.1.1.3. Road impacts vary with other policies? Whileoften development and deforestati<strong>on</strong> go hand in hand,the Acre state government in the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong> istrying to find ways for quality of life to increase whileNicholas Institute32


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesIf maintaining forest has little value, deforestati<strong>on</strong> canbe seen as an input into agricultural producti<strong>on</strong> with acost of clearing. It may create an asset used for severalyears that can appreciate or depreciate and sometimesbe sold. Such investment decisi<strong>on</strong>s will be shaped by theavailability and cost of credit, titling rules, and tenuresecurity (see next secti<strong>on</strong>) plus general ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s,such as inflati<strong>on</strong>.In these frameworks, any changes in key factors thatincrease agricultural profits <strong>on</strong> newly deforested landwill increase deforestati<strong>on</strong>. <strong>The</strong> evidence below firstaddresses this straightforward predicti<strong>on</strong> and then c<strong>on</strong>siderscomplexities: sec<strong>on</strong>d-order effects, different typesof producers, and endogeneity.3.2.1. Case Evidence3.2.1.1. Profit-driven deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Agricultural profitrises with prices of outputs (crops, livestock products)and falls with prices of inputs (chemicals, labor), as c<strong>on</strong>sistentlyobserved (see Angelsen and Kaimowitz 1999;Pfaff 1999; Barbier and Burgess 2001a; Geist and Lambin2002; Rudel et al. 2000; Wibowo and Byr<strong>on</strong> 1999). Deforestati<strong>on</strong>has tracked, for instance, commodity prices ofmaize in Mexico (Barbier and Burgess 1996), soybeansin Brazil (Morten et al. 2008), and cocoa in West Africa.More recent is demand for biofuels from crops that canbe profitably cultivated in lands cleared of tropical forest,such as oil palm in the Indo-Malaysian forests andpotentially in the Amaz<strong>on</strong> and C<strong>on</strong>go (Fitzherbert et al.2008; Koh and Wilcove 2008). This producti<strong>on</strong> of biofuels<strong>on</strong> deforested lands results in a large “carb<strong>on</strong> debt”that is <strong>on</strong>ly paid back through substituti<strong>on</strong> for fossil fuelsover many years (Fargi<strong>on</strong>e et al. 2008; Gibbs et al. 2008).Where biofuels compete for agricultural land, they canin additi<strong>on</strong> also raise deforestati<strong>on</strong> by reducing crop supplyand increasing crop prices.Price signals can be transmitted through trade policy.Opening up of trade may increase or decrease deforestati<strong>on</strong>,respectively, in regi<strong>on</strong>s with or without comparativeadvantage in the producti<strong>on</strong> in questi<strong>on</strong> (Lopezand Galinato 2005). <str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> may also directly affect theprices, e.g., through price floors. Less directly, governmentpolicies shape macroec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s that canaffect domestic demand and producti<strong>on</strong> of agriculturalcommodities across multiple regi<strong>on</strong>s.In many tropical forest regi<strong>on</strong>s, the two key inputs toagricultural producti<strong>on</strong> are land and labor and thus the“price” of using agricultural land is influenced by tenureand taxati<strong>on</strong> policies, discussed in the next secti<strong>on</strong>, aswell as the labor costs involved in cutting and burningthe forest. Thus the existence of a labor market and thewage rate influence deforestati<strong>on</strong>, establishing the possibilityand cost of employing labor, including in light ofcompeting demands (Shively 2001). Active labor marketswith low wages can encourage clearing by reducingcosts of deforestati<strong>on</strong> and increasing the profitabilityof agriculture. C<strong>on</strong>versely, out-migrati<strong>on</strong> in search ofhigher wages may factor into reversals of net deforestati<strong>on</strong>in Central America and the Caribbean.In some regi<strong>on</strong>s, fertilizer and other agricultural chemicalsare important inputs, and their prices are expectedto be inversely correlated with agricultural profitability.Credit is yet another input to agriculture, with cheapercredit in general lowering the costs of agricultural producti<strong>on</strong>,thereby increasing profitability and the deriveddemand for agricultural land. Credit, machinery, andlabor, however, also are all inputs into forest management.Thus shifts in their prices affect returns both toagriculture and to forestry and impacts <strong>on</strong> relativereturns require specific study.“Agricultural technology” includes crop and livestockvarieties, planting and harvesting techniques, and managementstrategies (e.g., intercropping, pasture rotati<strong>on</strong>).Brazil has made significant public investments in agriculturalresearch and development to raise productivity,reduce risks (e.g., from pests and disease) and openmarkets (e.g., via phytosanitary measures) (see Arima etal. 2005 for example of cattle in Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>). Generally,while Angelsen and Kaimowitz (2001) rightly notethat labor-intensive technological change can reducepressure to clear forest when labor is a limiting factor,which can hold <strong>on</strong> a fr<strong>on</strong>tier, improved agriculturaltechnology, coupled with market integrati<strong>on</strong>, str<strong>on</strong>gcommodity prices, and easy access to land, has proved arecipe for rapid deforestati<strong>on</strong> (Cattaneo 2001; Mort<strong>on</strong> etal. 2006; Hecht 2005). 1818 Much of the empirical literature <strong>on</strong> pasture management in the Amaz<strong>on</strong>suggests that improved producti<strong>on</strong> technology encourages deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Reisand Margulis (1994) found that deforestati<strong>on</strong> rates were positively correlatedwith cattle density in a municipal-level analysis in the Amaz<strong>on</strong>. Using a CGEmodel, Cattaneo (2001) finds improvements in livestock technology providehighest returns to farmers but dramatically increase l<strong>on</strong>g-run deforestati<strong>on</strong>.Limits <strong>on</strong> financial resources and <strong>on</strong> physical inputs such as phosphates areindicated as factors that diminish the prospects of maintaining n<strong>on</strong>decreasinglevels of productivity in the majority of pastures in the regi<strong>on</strong> (Fearnside 2002).In a cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al analysis, Seidl et al. (2001) find negligible increase in pasturearea c<strong>on</strong>sequent to an increase in the size of the cattle herd but a much largerimpact of mechanizati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> forest clearing am<strong>on</strong>g farmers with a tractor, whichsupports the theoretical predicti<strong>on</strong> that labor-saving technological changepromotes deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Even in the situati<strong>on</strong> of labor scarcity that characterizesmany parts of the Amaz<strong>on</strong>, returns to labor in low-intensity livestock systemsexceed those in perennial agriculture or forest extracti<strong>on</strong> and lead small farmerstowards more forest clearing for pastures (Vosti et al. 2001). Integrati<strong>on</strong> of thefr<strong>on</strong>tier into regi<strong>on</strong>al markets leads to higher rates of deforestati<strong>on</strong> (Vosti et al.2001). Walker et al. (2000) find that following such market integrati<strong>on</strong> in partsof Western Amaz<strong>on</strong>, changes in the producer prices favored beef and milk overother cash crops and encouraged expansi<strong>on</strong> of pastures.Nicholas Institute34


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesGovernment provisi<strong>on</strong> of, or subsidies to, infrastructureand services such as processing plants and veterinarycare also can have impact. In the c<strong>on</strong>text of col<strong>on</strong>izati<strong>on</strong>projects, impact is magnified by migrati<strong>on</strong> and theresulting expansi<strong>on</strong> in the labor supply, as dem<strong>on</strong>stratedby rapid deforestati<strong>on</strong> within INCRA (Instituto Naci<strong>on</strong>alde Col<strong>on</strong>izaçao e Reforma Agrária) settlements inthe Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong> and transmigrati<strong>on</strong> settlements inInd<strong>on</strong>esia. Infrastructure and a labor influx have led todeforestati<strong>on</strong> even where biophysical c<strong>on</strong>straints deteragricultural producti<strong>on</strong> (Schneider et al. 2000; Murdiyarsoand Lebel 2007).3.2.1.2. Complexities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> affecting agricultural profitability<strong>on</strong> newly deforested land can also have indirecteffects <strong>on</strong> the same household or the fr<strong>on</strong>tier regi<strong>on</strong>in questi<strong>on</strong> or in other parts of the country. <strong>The</strong>se canreinforce or counteract the direct effects. This can beparticularly true where markets are “incomplete,” with asmall number of participants or with significant barriersto transacti<strong>on</strong>s.For example, increasing opportunities for off-farm laborgenerally increase wages and reduce labor allocated tofarming. That would be expected to decrease deforestati<strong>on</strong>.However, where credit markets are incomplete, itcould relax cash or capital c<strong>on</strong>straints <strong>on</strong> deforestati<strong>on</strong>.Yet where most households are engaged in labor-intensiveagriculture and are not clearing land for potentialfuture sale, relaxing cash c<strong>on</strong>straints could allow investmentsin more intensive and sustainable systems (Barrett1999). <strong>The</strong>re are even potential l<strong>on</strong>g-run general-equilibriumeffects of the development of off-farm labor marketswith urbanizati<strong>on</strong>, increasing income, and greaterregi<strong>on</strong>al demand for agricultural producti<strong>on</strong> (e.g., ofmilk and beef in the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>).It is useful to distinguish producers oriented towardscommercial producti<strong>on</strong> for nati<strong>on</strong>al or internati<strong>on</strong>almarkets from those oriented towards subsistence producti<strong>on</strong>supplemented with sales into the local market.<strong>The</strong> former—whether smallholders producing cocoa inWest Africa or c<strong>on</strong>glomerates developing oil palm plantati<strong>on</strong>sin Southeast Asia—may reduce deforestati<strong>on</strong> inresp<strong>on</strong>se to credit crunches and increased input costs(e.g., eliminati<strong>on</strong> of fertilizer subsidies). Yet the samec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s may counterintuitively raise deforestati<strong>on</strong>by the latter, e.g., by migrants forced out of agriculturein their regi<strong>on</strong>s of origin who relocate to forest fr<strong>on</strong>tiers.Agricultural policy in those regi<strong>on</strong>s—includingland tenure, insurance against climatic risk, and priceregimes—can have a critical influence <strong>on</strong> the forest fr<strong>on</strong>tierthrough its influence <strong>on</strong> migrati<strong>on</strong> decisi<strong>on</strong>s.Creating dynamic indirect effects from all of the driversnoted above, deforestati<strong>on</strong> itself can change ec<strong>on</strong>omicc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s and foster further deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Atthe farm level, cleared land may serve as collateral forlower-interest loans. At the regi<strong>on</strong>al scale, the resultingagricultural activities may attract services, processors,populati<strong>on</strong> and roads, reinforcing deforestati<strong>on</strong> (see forinstance Schneider 1995; Mertens et al. 2002; Kaimowitzand Smith 2001;Pfaff et al. 2007; and Pfaff, Robalino andHerrera 2009). It is widely believed that this type of selfreinforcingprocess applies to the deforestati<strong>on</strong> “poles”in the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>, even where the initial forestchanges may have been driven largely by policies.In c<strong>on</strong>sidering dynamics at this level, the possibilityof “forest transiti<strong>on</strong>s” is also of note. Developmentdynamics shift over time, and perhaps with the levelof income or development, and may imply a shift fromnet forest loss to net gain. Some such shifts in directi<strong>on</strong>are observed. Key comp<strong>on</strong>ents of such dynamics maybe more intensive producti<strong>on</strong> in more productive areasal<strong>on</strong>g with out-migrati<strong>on</strong> from and perhaps targetedincentives for forest in marginal regi<strong>on</strong>s.While rising income likely raises commodities demand,it could also allow investment in more intensive agricultureand could increase demand for envir<strong>on</strong>mentalservices and products provided by standing forests(see Foster and Rosenzweig 2003). Further, it has beenobserved that in most developed countries deforestati<strong>on</strong>increased but then decreased as income grew (see, e.g.,Claws<strong>on</strong> 1979). 19 Deforestati<strong>on</strong> has stopped in a numberof countries and forest area has been increasing not<strong>on</strong>ly in Costa Rica but also in countries such as the U.S.In looking for such patterns, some have found that the“turning point,” or the income level where deforestati<strong>on</strong>rates start to fall after previously rising with incomegrowth, appears to vary across countries and to dependup<strong>on</strong> other c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s such as the distributi<strong>on</strong> of wealthand political freedoms (Bhattarai and Hammig 2001).However, we must recognize the importance of trade insatisfying local commodities demand based up<strong>on</strong> n<strong>on</strong>localresource use and deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Pfaff and Walker(2010) discuss the historical case of the New Englandregi<strong>on</strong> of the U.S., which from the early 1800s to theearly 1900s significantly reforested while growing inboth income and populati<strong>on</strong>. It could appear to suggest19 Within discussi<strong>on</strong>s of envir<strong>on</strong>mental degradati<strong>on</strong>, this pattern of risingthen falling degradati<strong>on</strong> al<strong>on</strong>g the path of development is sometimes called an“envir<strong>on</strong>mental Kuznets curve” (see early evidence c<strong>on</strong>cerning this possibility inGrossman and Krueger 1995). <strong>The</strong> evidence for such paths varies by pollutantand by study. <strong>The</strong>re are good reas<strong>on</strong>s to believe that under some c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong>ewould expect such a path, yet there is no reas<strong>on</strong> to assume that it will occureverywhere (Pfaff et al. 2004).Nicholas Institute35


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativesthat deforestati<strong>on</strong> reversals are to be expected, as forestscarcity did motivate efficient use of wood and woodsubstitutes. Yet significant imports of agriculture fromthe midwestern regi<strong>on</strong> addressed food demand, at lowercost after canals and railroads linked the regi<strong>on</strong>s, and significantimports of timber from southern, midwestern,and northwestern regi<strong>on</strong>s also addressed local demands.Thus, without bringing in commodities, something notpossible at the global scale, New England’s regi<strong>on</strong>aldeforestati<strong>on</strong> reversal may have been greatly lessened oreliminated.In light of these ideas, Pfaff and Walker (2010) c<strong>on</strong>siderthe case of the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>. Some partsof the regi<strong>on</strong> are reforesting, and c<strong>on</strong>sistent with thisview, there will be specializati<strong>on</strong> within the regi<strong>on</strong> withsome areas producing and selling to others. Yet takingthe Amaz<strong>on</strong> as the regi<strong>on</strong> in questi<strong>on</strong>, if anythingit appears that it exports products to the rest of Brazil,at least <strong>on</strong> net, which would not predict deforestati<strong>on</strong>reversal. <strong>The</strong>n taking the country as the regi<strong>on</strong>, not <strong>on</strong>lysoy but also timber and beef are being exported to othercountries. This may lower threats within those countriesbut would not appear to suggest that income will lowerAmaz<strong>on</strong> clearing.3.2.2. Looking AheadWhere deforesting for agricultural producti<strong>on</strong> is profitable,perhaps the clearest route to reducing deforestati<strong>on</strong>is to reduce output prices. This has happened viaec<strong>on</strong>omic recessi<strong>on</strong>, overvaluati<strong>on</strong> of exchange rates,and c<strong>on</strong>flict (Fearnside 2005c; Sunderlin and Pokam2002;Lopez and Galinato 2005), n<strong>on</strong>e of which can berecommended as <strong>REDD</strong> policy. Demand management(see 1.4 above) is a more politically viable approachbut with less of a track record. It could be employed asdomestic policy. For example, major beef processors insouthern Brazil recently agreed to a Greenpeace plan notto purchase cattle from newly deforested areas. Governmentscould also try to increase profitability elsewhere,e.g., targeting marginal lands. That may be <strong>on</strong>e approachto managing demand for biofuels through various permittingprocesses (Searchinger et al. 2008).<strong>The</strong>re are more opportunities to change deforestati<strong>on</strong>trajectories in regi<strong>on</strong>s where limited access or otherbiophysical c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s mean agriculture is marginallyprofitable with subsidies. <strong>The</strong>re carb<strong>on</strong> payments couldcompensate for eliminati<strong>on</strong> of those subsidies, especiallywith the clarificati<strong>on</strong> of tenure and tax laws. Planningto avoid col<strong>on</strong>izati<strong>on</strong> projects and infrastructure inmarginal locati<strong>on</strong>s could be <strong>on</strong>e “win-win” for regi<strong>on</strong>alec<strong>on</strong>omies and global carb<strong>on</strong> emissi<strong>on</strong>s.Improving agricultural technology can raise deforestati<strong>on</strong>but this does not suggest that agricultural researchand development should be discouraged, given effects <strong>on</strong>malnourishment (v<strong>on</strong> Braun 2008), decreased reliance<strong>on</strong> forest biomass as a key input to agriculture (Benhin2006), 20 facilitating c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for forest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>(Ewers et al. 2009), and even potential large-scale reducti<strong>on</strong>sin anthropogenic carb<strong>on</strong> emissi<strong>on</strong>s (Wise et al.2009). <strong>The</strong> key is to couple such increased productivitywith tenure, tax, credit, infrastructure, and other policiesthat inhibit agricultural expansi<strong>on</strong> into forest areas andsupport sustainable management of standing forests.3.3. Land TenureTenure regimes in which those who clear acquire squatter’srights and later title have l<strong>on</strong>g promoted deforestati<strong>on</strong>(Fearnside 2005a). Clearing may be productive,but even clearing not leading to profitable use mayallow acquisiti<strong>on</strong> of title, facilitating credit and/or futureresales. Clearing may even be required to obtain permanenttitle. That clearly encourages deforestati<strong>on</strong>.Lack of secure tenure matters too. Risk of losing forestthrough expropriati<strong>on</strong> reduces the incentives for l<strong>on</strong>gtermsustainable management. It can be difficult for individualsand even communities (H<strong>on</strong>ey-Rosés 2009) tostop expropriati<strong>on</strong> through illegal logging where timbertrespass can occur in private forest, a risk that varies bysetting but yet is widespread. Illegal logging is believedto be a significant part of timber harvest across all majortropical forest regi<strong>on</strong>s. Although estimates vary, illegallogging in Latin America is not uncomm<strong>on</strong> (seeGuertin 2003’s examinati<strong>on</strong> of trade flows between LatinAmerica and developed countries, and examples cited inC<strong>on</strong>treras-Hermosilla 2000). It includes everything fromtrespass to lack of requisite paperwork. In Camero<strong>on</strong>,the illegal logging statistics often combine and c<strong>on</strong>fusedifferent types of violati<strong>on</strong>s by actors operating at differentscales (Cerutti and Tacc<strong>on</strong>i 2008). Yet clearly therisk of illegal logging is a barrier to sustainable forestmanagement (Putz et al. 2009).Defending tenure is costly. Owners choose am<strong>on</strong>g landuses, often clearing for agriculture or grazing, plantati<strong>on</strong>s,and unmanaged native forest land or protectedreserves and the costs of site protecti<strong>on</strong> affect the relative20 Clearing forest for agriculture often provides both an immediate cash in-flow(from sale of timber) and short-term enhancement of soil fertility. This is key tothe ec<strong>on</strong>omic logic of cattle ranching in the Amaz<strong>on</strong> and oil palm plantati<strong>on</strong>s inSoutheast Asia. Small farmers also rely <strong>on</strong> the fertility boost from burning or rottingforest biomass. Traditi<strong>on</strong>al shifting cultivati<strong>on</strong> systems sustain forest cover<strong>on</strong> a landscape scale, but the additi<strong>on</strong> of stressors such as populati<strong>on</strong> growth andintroduced plant species can make small-scale slash-and-burn agriculture thefirst step to large-scale and permanent deforestati<strong>on</strong>.Nicholas Institute36


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativesreturns from land uses. While carb<strong>on</strong>-based paymentscould increase rents to holding or establishing forests,any such rents must overcome the higher site protecti<strong>on</strong>costs for forested land. Private costs of protecti<strong>on</strong> areimportant when government enforcement of propertyownership tends to be poor due to budget c<strong>on</strong>straints,remoteness of forests, and corrupti<strong>on</strong> in forest sectors.Three forms of illegal logging threaten the native forestsand producti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>REDD</strong>. First, small-scale timbertrespass can occur <strong>on</strong> privately owned forest at almostany time. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, large-scale illegal pulse harvesting ofnative (often public) forests occurs when prices and costsmake these activities profitable. Third, when forests areharvested, unsustainable (and illegal) logging practicescan reduce soil productivity and carb<strong>on</strong> storage—examplesare damage to residual trees and the destructi<strong>on</strong> ofsoil resources through site-insensitive logging and harvesting<strong>on</strong>ly the best-formed, largest, or more valuabletrees rather than following government-mandated cuttingguidelines (Putz 2005).Interventi<strong>on</strong>s affecting land tenure and land marketscould both facilitate implementati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>REDD</strong> (by clarifyingrights and resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities) and directly generate<strong>REDD</strong> (by discouraging deforestati<strong>on</strong> to establish ownershipand obtain credit). Fundamentally, deforestati<strong>on</strong>should not be rewarded with or required for title. Forinstance, when the routes for new infrastructure areannounced, deforestati<strong>on</strong> can precede the installati<strong>on</strong> ofthe new infrastructure because forward-looking actorsclear for title in advance of rising land demand. 21 Thissort of liquidati<strong>on</strong> of forest for the private gains fromresale, e.g., is avoidable through policy. 22 Still, incompleteand overlapping property records that do not recognizetraditi<strong>on</strong>al land tenure c<strong>on</strong>tinue to provide opportunitiesfor powerful actors to acquire titles to vast tracksof land in this way (Fearnside 2005a; Brito and Barreto2009).Government detecti<strong>on</strong> rates and fines for illegal loggingmatter and could be increased with <strong>REDD</strong> payments.For a private landowner, this could lower the costs of siteprotecti<strong>on</strong> and increase forest returns. This also reducesthe supply of illegally obtained timber, increasing thereturns to holding forests. However, governments incountries with large publicly owned tropical forests orlarge and remote privately owned forests often do notpunish forest crimes, and when they do, fines are lowor never collected. Further, in most developing tropical21 Acre Sustainable Development Program registered all land claims al<strong>on</strong>groute of BR-364 to Cruzeiro do Sul before paving.22 Several of the proposals to the Fundo Amazônia focus <strong>on</strong> sorting out landtenure and titling, as a prerequisite to <strong>REDD</strong>.countries the return captured by government from theforest harvest is low and thus motivati<strong>on</strong> for the governmentto protect these forests is also low (noting thatreas<strong>on</strong>s for low returns include both transport costs andsite protecti<strong>on</strong> costs). In principle, <strong>REDD</strong> payment toforest landowners may raise forest-related tax bases sogovernments view preserved forests as important revenuesources.3.3.1. Case Evidence3.3.1.1. Costly protecti<strong>on</strong> and investment disincentives. Ifexpropriati<strong>on</strong> of land is possible, actors are less likely tomake investments. This could be public expropriati<strong>on</strong>,such as for a protected area, or private expropriati<strong>on</strong> bysquatters under an “adverse tenure” system—<strong>on</strong>e whomakes use of the land can acquire possessi<strong>on</strong>. In Brazil,expropriati<strong>on</strong> risk is higher if land is not in a “beneficialuse” (Alst<strong>on</strong> et al. 2000). <strong>The</strong> literature shows thatthese risks create str<strong>on</strong>g disincentives for forestry (Mendelsohn1994; Barbier and Burgess 2001b; Zhang 2001;Amacher et al. 2008a). Many of these studies find thatunder high property-rights insecurities, i.e., a lack ofsecure tenure, the potential for timber trespass <strong>on</strong> privateland may render forest management and protecti<strong>on</strong>not worthwhile relative to agriculture and grazing.<strong>The</strong> impact of expropriati<strong>on</strong> risk <strong>on</strong> deforestati<strong>on</strong> hasbeen found in numerous cases, including Armsberg(1998), Alst<strong>on</strong> et al. (2000), Bohn and Deac<strong>on</strong> (2000),C<strong>on</strong>treras-Hermosilla (2000), Blaser and Douglas(2000), and van Kooten et al. (1999). Alst<strong>on</strong> et al. (2000)argue that de facto in the Amaz<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly land clearing forat least five years protects against such risk. Blaser andDouglas (2000) have made the case that under currentpolicy, expropriati<strong>on</strong> risk deters intensive managementfor tropical forests. Wibowo and Byr<strong>on</strong> (1999) arguethere is a risk of evicti<strong>on</strong> faced by landowners who investfor the l<strong>on</strong>g term.Land tenure regimes differ across countries, though.Sometimes they add to uncertainty landowners haveabout forest producti<strong>on</strong>. Within Amaz<strong>on</strong>ia, land is typicallyformally settled and even sometimes titled throughgovernment acti<strong>on</strong> in designated areas, informally settledby those with minimal rights, and squatted by thosewith the least amount of rights. Individuals with landin multiple regimes clearly perceive differences in landrents and values. Merry et al. (2008) show the type ofproperty rights regime is critical in assessing the valuethat households attach to holding forests, while Amacheret al. (2009a) find that property rights regimes affect theincentives to sell wood from smallholder plots. This isNicholas Institute37


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativessignificant, as close to 20% of all removals in Amaz<strong>on</strong>iaare from smallholder lots (Nepstad et al. 2004).In Africa, land tenure regimes are even more complicated,with many influences, including communal andfamilial customs, defining tenure and use of land as wellas state and statutory rights imposed by distant centralgovernments. Due to the complexity of decentralizedtitling in many countries, formal registrati<strong>on</strong> of landrights is rare (Cotula et al. 2004). In additi<strong>on</strong>, propertyrightsinsecurities and the need for local site protecti<strong>on</strong>to defend <strong>on</strong>e’s tenure, which are comm<strong>on</strong> in LatinAmerica and Asia, are present also here, and all of theseincrease incentives to clear forests for short-term agriculturalreturns.Other Amaz<strong>on</strong>ian analyses cite incomplete land marketsand/or real estate speculati<strong>on</strong> as c<strong>on</strong>tributing factors todeforestati<strong>on</strong> (Fujisaka et al. 1996; Fearnside 2001, 2002;Kirby et al. 2006). 23 Speculati<strong>on</strong> is linked with acquiringtenure through clearing for cattle pasture, which establishesboundaries (Hecht 1993; Fearnside 2005a). Thiswas often cited in the 1980s, when subsidies and inflati<strong>on</strong>made land a good investment (Moran 1993). Inflati<strong>on</strong>erodes the value of alternatives and c<strong>on</strong>tributes tothe retirement of real debt acquired through real estateloans (Just and Miranowski 1993). When real land pricesmay rise faster than real returns <strong>on</strong> alternatives, investmentsin real estate (here deforestati<strong>on</strong>) is attractive.Land tenure regimes can link indirectly to costly privatesite protecti<strong>on</strong>. Hotte (2005) and Clarke et al. (1993)examine agricultural land users’ costly private enforcement,such as building fences or expending resources toobtain formal title. Hotte (2005) also shows c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s inwhich a landowner lacking clear rights has an incentiveto overexploit land to prevent returns being captured byillegal trespassers. Miceli et al. (2002) analyze the meritsof titling systems in resolving land claims, finding thatformal title provides incentives to protect while informaltitle does not. Generally, when property rights are notsecure and timber prices are reas<strong>on</strong>ably high, we expectillegal logging to erode returns from carb<strong>on</strong> storage ingovernment-held or private forest areas.3.3.1.2. Migrati<strong>on</strong> and populati<strong>on</strong>. Insecure propertyrights are believed to affect populati<strong>on</strong>’s impacts <strong>on</strong> agriculturalforested fr<strong>on</strong>tiers. Perz et al. (2005), Pan-Amaz<strong>on</strong>,correlate rapid populati<strong>on</strong> growth in rural areaswith deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Fertility rates are high but in-migrati<strong>on</strong>is the main driver of the populati<strong>on</strong> growth, andboth are partly driven by tenure insecurity (Carr 2004;Carr et al. 2006; Bilsborrow 2002). Other studies identifytenure as a “pull factor,” with people migrating to areaswhere access has been newly established and they canobtain their own plots (Amacher et al. 1998; Barnes etal. 2002; Merry and Amacher 2008).Amacher et al. (2008a) examine endogenous costlysite protecti<strong>on</strong> by landowners, showing how migrati<strong>on</strong>pressure, insecure property rights, and costly enforcement(public and private) determine land returns.This addresses disagreement about wages, populati<strong>on</strong>growth, and property rights (Barbier and Burgess 2001b;Angelsen and Kaimowitz 1999; Shively 2001; Shively andPagiola 2004). Effects <strong>on</strong> incentives to hold or establishforests depend <strong>on</strong> whether “push” effects of populati<strong>on</strong>growth are larger or smaller than effects <strong>on</strong> the availabilityof labor for the protecti<strong>on</strong> of forest, both locally andby large landowners.<strong>REDD</strong> could seek to influence deforestati<strong>on</strong> throughdemographic channels, including populati<strong>on</strong> growthrates, migrati<strong>on</strong> patterns, and the spatial distributi<strong>on</strong> ofpopulati<strong>on</strong>. Pfaff (1999) shows that this spatial distributi<strong>on</strong>affects Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>ian regi<strong>on</strong>s’ deforestati<strong>on</strong>rates. Deforestati<strong>on</strong> per pers<strong>on</strong> is lower for c<strong>on</strong>centratedpopulati<strong>on</strong>s. 24 Dynamics vary globally but in most ofLatin America, internal migrati<strong>on</strong> is the key in populati<strong>on</strong>growth <strong>on</strong> the forest fr<strong>on</strong>tier and could be influencedby policies that increase the desirability of urbandestinati<strong>on</strong>s. Tenure security interacts with migrati<strong>on</strong> inmyriad ways, e.g., by facilitating credit for intensificati<strong>on</strong>or c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> to cattle that reduced the need for labor(Carr 2004).3.3.1.3. Plantati<strong>on</strong>s. <strong>The</strong>re is growing use of land usefor plantati<strong>on</strong>s, some privately protected when tenureis less secure. Potential carb<strong>on</strong> storage could be quite23 Most studies of property-values impacts <strong>on</strong> land-use choices in the Amaz<strong>on</strong>use proxies due to data limitati<strong>on</strong>s. Several have assumed that property valuescan be represented by distance to markets and to other infrastructure (Alst<strong>on</strong>et al. 1995; Mertens and Lambin 2000). Chomitz and Thomas (2003) use cattlestocking rates as a proxy for land value, arguing that higher-valued land is usedmore intensively. Specific determinants of transacti<strong>on</strong>s in Amaz<strong>on</strong>ian landmarkets that have been identified include soil quality (Moran et al. 2002), type oftitle (Vosti et al. 2001), extent of and access to road system (Fujisaka et al. 1996),and percent of land in pasture (Mertens et al. 2002). Ozorio and Campari (1995)note that small farms in the Amaz<strong>on</strong> are not just agricultural producti<strong>on</strong> unitsbut also key for home producti<strong>on</strong> and as residences for family who earn off-farmincome.24 While areas with high populati<strong>on</strong> densities generally have experiencedmore deforestati<strong>on</strong>, this might be because other c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s like high agriculturalyields encouraged both populati<strong>on</strong> growth and deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Another possibledynamic is that deforestati<strong>on</strong> can drive the changes in populati<strong>on</strong>, e.g., deforestati<strong>on</strong>and development encourages immigrati<strong>on</strong> to a regi<strong>on</strong>. One would liketo analyze the impacts of the shifts in populati<strong>on</strong> not due to deforestati<strong>on</strong> orcomm<strong>on</strong> causes such as yields. A third issue related to the empirical associati<strong>on</strong>sbetween populati<strong>on</strong> and deforestati<strong>on</strong> arises with data from the Food andAgriculture Organizati<strong>on</strong> (FAO) of the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s. Historically, FAO hascompiled statistics <strong>on</strong> forest cover that are reported by country governments,and when they were not available, FAO predicted forest cover with a model thatincluded populati<strong>on</strong>.Nicholas Institute38


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativeshigh. ITTO (2005) estimates that there are now nearly45 milli<strong>on</strong> hectares of forest plantati<strong>on</strong>s in Asia and thePacific. Both Latin America (5.6 milli<strong>on</strong> hectares) andAfrica (825,000 hectares) have smaller investments butthere are private and community-managed plantati<strong>on</strong>sin India, Bangladesh, and Ind<strong>on</strong>esia in additi<strong>on</strong> to Brazil(Albers 1996; Hyde et al. 1996). Plantati<strong>on</strong>s could be animportant source of timber from land previously bothgrazed and aband<strong>on</strong>ed (FAO 2005). Malaysia is providingan incentive to establish forest plantati<strong>on</strong>s to relievepressure <strong>on</strong> natural forests.An issue raised by this idea is that public native forestand private plantati<strong>on</strong>s could compete with each otherin land and output markets (this may depend <strong>on</strong> useof degraded lands). <strong>REDD</strong> could potentially be eithersupported or undermined by policies affecting returns<strong>on</strong> plantati<strong>on</strong>s (c<strong>on</strong>cerning impacts of timber prices,Amacher et al. [2008a] show land use resp<strong>on</strong>ding toreturns at the margin). Which land use does relativelybetter under <strong>REDD</strong> will depend <strong>on</strong> the way that paymentsto landowners are structured. If carb<strong>on</strong> paymentsare based strictly <strong>on</strong> forest growth, i.e., carb<strong>on</strong> uptake(not c<strong>on</strong>sidering a penalty if forests are cleared for plantati<strong>on</strong>s),plantati<strong>on</strong>s can generate greater payments thannatural or native (often over-mature) forests. Also whenproperty rights are insecure, plantati<strong>on</strong>s become moreeasily protected than natural forests. Whatever the reas<strong>on</strong>,this type of crowding out represents a potentialunintended c<strong>on</strong>sequence of <strong>REDD</strong> that could lower provisi<strong>on</strong>of global public goods in the l<strong>on</strong>g run.Generally, renewable forest resources need not beexhausted. Resources can be managed (Amaz<strong>on</strong>ian forestssee in Whitmore 1991; Vincent 1990; Veríssimo etal. 1992; Uhl et al. 1997; Boltz et al. 2001). In the past,there has been <strong>on</strong>ly limited uptake of the best managementpractices in the harvest of timber—let al<strong>on</strong>e l<strong>on</strong>gtermsustainable forest management—due to factorsincluding the lack of credit, uncertain land tenure, andcompetiti<strong>on</strong> from illegal logging (Applegate et al. 2004;Bacha 2003; Putz et al. 2000; Uhl et al. 1997; Veríssimoet al. 2002).3.3.2. Looking AheadWhile <strong>REDD</strong> payments could bring the public benefitsof forest to the attenti<strong>on</strong> of private landowners, they willnot necessarily make forest ownership profitable whereit is difficult to protect forests from squatters and illegallogging. Where forest rents did not involve the benefitof <strong>REDD</strong> payments, Wibowo and Byr<strong>on</strong> (1999), Barbierand Burgess (2001a), and Bohn and Deac<strong>on</strong> (2000) findin cross-country studies that insecure property rightsand lack of government enforcement were both highlysignificant predictors of the lack of investment in thedevelopment of forest capital (e.g., by reforestati<strong>on</strong>).Clear rights may be essentially necessary for such investmentsin forest, which would reduce deforestati<strong>on</strong> andgenerate <strong>REDD</strong>. Yet, as rights can also facilitate investmentsin producti<strong>on</strong> (fences, perennial crops), they maynot be sufficient. Also of uncertain impact are marketprices for timber. <strong>The</strong>y increase returns from illegallogging, decreasing incentives for landowners to holdforested lands, yet at the same time increase the returnsfrom legal forest management, thus directly increasingthe incentive to maintain forest.Payments for <strong>REDD</strong> will also need to create the rightincentives for owners to hold land in forest for sometime. In most of the tropical countries of Africa, Asia,and Latin and Central America with potential for largescalecarb<strong>on</strong> credits, incentives depend <strong>on</strong> the extent ofillegal logging and <strong>on</strong> property-rights insecurities, linkedto the ability and willingness of budget-c<strong>on</strong>strained governmentsto enforce right of ownership. Insecure tenurelowers <strong>REDD</strong> incentives as protecting <strong>on</strong>e’s site translatesinto a high cost of participati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>REDD</strong>. Perhapssigning up to generate <strong>REDD</strong> could even help to establishrights. More generally, details of <strong>REDD</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tracts,e.g., liability for outcomes of illegal incursi<strong>on</strong>s, will affect<strong>REDD</strong>.In summary, the impacts of <strong>REDD</strong> payments up<strong>on</strong> landuse, and ultimately <strong>on</strong> deforestati<strong>on</strong>, clearly will depend<strong>on</strong> property risks as well as the effects of payments up<strong>on</strong>the returns that landowners receive from each of severalcompeting land uses. Payments could be structured withall of these issues in mind.3.4. Corrupti<strong>on</strong>Government corrupti<strong>on</strong> is undeniably present in developingcountries with large forest areas and is a c<strong>on</strong>straintfor <strong>REDD</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tracts, most clearly as linked to c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s(see discussi<strong>on</strong> of c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s in 3.3). Analystshave observed loss of forest rents due to corrupti<strong>on</strong>(e.g., Human Rights Watch 2009). Because the precisenature of corrupti<strong>on</strong> differs across countries and becausethe relati<strong>on</strong>ship between corrupti<strong>on</strong> and stability is alsolikely to vary (see, e.g., discussi<strong>on</strong> in Ferreira and Vincent2010), the best design of a carb<strong>on</strong> emissi<strong>on</strong>s programswithin <strong>on</strong>e country may not apply to any othercountry. This has implicati<strong>on</strong>s for <strong>REDD</strong> that are oftenignored (but were touched <strong>on</strong> by Karsenty 2008’s recentreview).Nicholas Institute39


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesCorrupti<strong>on</strong> is a complex and multifaceted problem thatis not easily c<strong>on</strong>trollable, even for well-meaning governments.For forestry and particularly forest c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s,corrupti<strong>on</strong> is usually seen in <strong>on</strong>e of two forms: largefirms with political power may influence governmentpolicies or choices about c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s at early stages ofthe process; or smaller firms may bribe state officials tooverlook c<strong>on</strong>tracts’ stipulati<strong>on</strong>s during any of the processesinvolved, i.e., harvesting and milling and thenexporting wood.In a corrupt setting, even with effort to restrict this,<strong>REDD</strong> payments could simply increase equilibriumbribes and then transfer wealth from the forest owner toillegal loggers and government officials whose objectivesdo not align with the central government promoting<strong>REDD</strong>. While it may seem compelling just to overlookcorrupti<strong>on</strong> and expect that carb<strong>on</strong> payments will supportincreased forest despite all these issues, even costlyre-design to reduce corrupti<strong>on</strong> may be better than leavingcorrupt actors unchecked.3.4.1. Case EvidenceIn the forest sector, corrupti<strong>on</strong> is documented in Africa,Asia, and Latin America, typically via bribery of governmentofficials to overlook infracti<strong>on</strong>s including harvestingmore than allowed (C<strong>on</strong>treras-Hermosilla [2002]offers a review that points to bribery and corrupti<strong>on</strong>where forests are sold throughout the world). Bribeshave been singled out as part of forestry in tropicalcountries, c<strong>on</strong>founding central governments’ attemptsto promulgate forest policy (see Palmer 2005 and Smithet al. 2003 for Asian cases, and Siebert and Elwert 2004for cases in Africa). Officials accept bribes for allowingillegal timber trade in Tanzania and Camero<strong>on</strong>, countrieswith large government forests, where the risk ofdetecting illegal logging is low and enforcement is lacking(<strong>on</strong>ly 4% of offenders are punished, while 20% ofcitati<strong>on</strong>s are typically dropped). Other tropical forestedcountries with similar circumstances include Ghana andLiberia. In Benin, an arid country, enforcement of forestrights is low and illegal logging is high largely due toscope for bribery.A large ec<strong>on</strong>omic literature comments <strong>on</strong> situati<strong>on</strong>swhere corrupti<strong>on</strong> must be reduced. Jain (2001) findscorrupti<strong>on</strong> when discreti<strong>on</strong>ary power is held by governmentofficials in positi<strong>on</strong>s with access to bribes, whenthere are high rents to government-owned resources,and when the probability of detecti<strong>on</strong> or punishment islow. For a government with sufficient financial resources,however, from this perspective it appears that corrupti<strong>on</strong>could be limited by employing a well-financed str<strong>on</strong>genforcement system.Jain (2001) further suggests that high wages paid to publicofficials can be effective in curbing corrupti<strong>on</strong> if thereis a relatively high probability of detecti<strong>on</strong> of bribery. Aproblem with raising wages, however, is that they canlead to greater government debt and, thus, less ability toenforce property rights and thus maintain forest returnsat high enough levels (see 1.3 above) to ensure <strong>REDD</strong>emissi<strong>on</strong>s reducti<strong>on</strong>s.Limited financial resources and distant resources makesthese efforts difficult. C<strong>on</strong>treras-Hermosilla (2002)finds high corrupti<strong>on</strong> with underpaid government forestinspectors. This analysis also highlights complexregulati<strong>on</strong>s involving property rights, bureaucratic stepsrequired in obtaining permits to use or establish productiveforests, low penalties for illegal logging, and clearlythe open-access nature of native forests.Detecti<strong>on</strong> of bribery is not enough. Unless penalties arehigh, the incentives to cheat by inspectors and <strong>on</strong> thepart of the illegal loggers will be high regardless of theinspector’s base wage. This is because the harvester willalways be made better off paying the bribe, given thatexpected costs as a result of being detected bribing bythe central government are lower than his expected costsfrom <strong>on</strong>ly h<strong>on</strong>est acti<strong>on</strong>.Mishra (2004) argues that penalties and inspector compensati<strong>on</strong>can work in the same or opposite directi<strong>on</strong>sin affecting bribery incentives and that the <strong>on</strong>ly way totruly eradicate bribery is by having high enough wagesfor government officials. Finally, competiti<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>gfirms has been shown clearly to decrease bribery (Barbieret al. 2005; Delacote 2008). Fair bidding processescould be a priority for <strong>REDD</strong> to succeed (Barbier et al.2005’s open ec<strong>on</strong>omy model shows corrupting influenceof forest exploitati<strong>on</strong> lobbies).For m<strong>on</strong>itoring, Mishra (2004) suggests that the mostimportant reform is to have multiple horiz<strong>on</strong>tal levelsof government m<strong>on</strong>itoring use of government resources,i.e., “overlapping jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s” in Mishra’s terms (notingimplicati<strong>on</strong>s for detecti<strong>on</strong> probabilities, optimal penaltylevels, and the costs of m<strong>on</strong>itoring as well). <strong>The</strong>n morethan <strong>on</strong>e logging inspector is involved with a given harvestingsetting and a logging inspector from <strong>on</strong>e departmentcan be compensated for reporting bribery byanother official.Yet different levels of government may have differentobjectives. Local officials may attach more value to woodNicholas Institute40


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativesfrom their jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s. Thus <strong>on</strong>e important designquesti<strong>on</strong> is how carb<strong>on</strong> payments arrive to the localities.If higher levels of governments collect revenue, and thiscan be shared with the localities, then there may be waysof bringing the incentives of all governments in line forthe generati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>REDD</strong>.3.4.2. Looking AheadC<strong>on</strong>sidering policy design, assuming officials can bebribed, Delacote (2008) finds corrupti<strong>on</strong> may inducelarger c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s and less stringent use regulati<strong>on</strong>s.Amacher et al. (2008b) c<strong>on</strong>sider harvester behavior anda government c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong> design with corrupti<strong>on</strong>, comparingthis to when officials cannot be bribed. Wherecorrupti<strong>on</strong> is c<strong>on</strong>trolled, c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s can be larger androyalties smaller as enforcement is more efficient andcheaper. Yet blindly increasing royalties or reducingc<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong> size may cause changes in bribes that underminec<strong>on</strong>trol. C<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong> design clearly should reflectsuch issues as real c<strong>on</strong>straints.C<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong> design involving envir<strong>on</strong>mentally sensitiveharvesting regulati<strong>on</strong>s also should bear in mind the issueof bribery. Generally, moving forward with carb<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>sfor <strong>REDD</strong> is sensible <strong>on</strong>ly with an understandingof the potential for corrupti<strong>on</strong>. Corrupti<strong>on</strong> usuallyreinforces bad aspects of designs and the revenue problemsfaced by governments tend to make these aspectsworse. <strong>The</strong> ultimate successes of <strong>REDD</strong> within this area,in terms of deforestati<strong>on</strong>, forest degradati<strong>on</strong>, and localwelfare, surely will be a functi<strong>on</strong> of the existing levelsof corrupti<strong>on</strong> at all levels of government, as well as thegovernment debt, and last but not least, both local andfederal governments’ ability to govern within fr<strong>on</strong>tierregi<strong>on</strong>s through revised m<strong>on</strong>itoring and enforcementstrategies.Nicholas Institute41


Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong>Neither Too Easy Nor Too HardTwo opposite schools of thought are emergingregarding the role of internati<strong>on</strong>al forest carb<strong>on</strong> and<strong>REDD</strong> in U.S. and global climate policy. One assertsthat opportunities to reduce carb<strong>on</strong> emissi<strong>on</strong>s are cheapand also abundant. Thus, if they generate carb<strong>on</strong> credits,those credits could “flood” cap-and-trade programsand reduce the incentive to invest in emissi<strong>on</strong>s reducti<strong>on</strong>within rich countries. <strong>The</strong> other <strong>on</strong>e asserts that reducingglobal deforestati<strong>on</strong> is so daunting that significantreducti<strong>on</strong> of this type is nearly impossible.<strong>The</strong> first view is guided in part by the noti<strong>on</strong> that the costof stopping deforestati<strong>on</strong> exactly equals the opportunitycost of the alternative land use (e.g., revenues generatedby agriculture). In this view, these revenues may also beperceived often to be low (though they are not alwaysso and can be very high) which suggests that c<strong>on</strong>servingforests is relatively cheap. This view ties in with c<strong>on</strong>cernsthat errors in negotiated emissi<strong>on</strong> baselines couldyield many credits not backed by emissi<strong>on</strong> reducti<strong>on</strong>s.<strong>The</strong> sec<strong>on</strong>d view appears to be guided by the failures ofprevious efforts to reduce deforestati<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>cernsthat many countries still lack the governance capacity toeffectively implement new such policy programs.Reality lies in between these extremes. <strong>The</strong>re are opportunitiesto avoid deforestati<strong>on</strong> in the tropics at low costcompared to other efforts to reduce GHG emissi<strong>on</strong>s.Yet claims about the opportunities immediately availablehave likely been overstated. Actual costs of reducingdeforestati<strong>on</strong> include costs to reform land tenure,to distribute payments, and to establish, manage, andm<strong>on</strong>itor protected areas. C<strong>on</strong>tinued demand for woodand agricultural products, populati<strong>on</strong> pressures, weakgovernance, and other instituti<strong>on</strong>al factors are limits <strong>on</strong>short-run reducti<strong>on</strong>s in deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Thus, comm<strong>on</strong>lyused measures of opportunity costs do not indicate typicalcosts, but rather a minimum or lower-bound <strong>on</strong> thecost for implementing <strong>REDD</strong>.This realizati<strong>on</strong> could lead <strong>on</strong>e towards the sec<strong>on</strong>d view,and indeed reviewing the results of past efforts to halttropical deforestati<strong>on</strong> is sobering. Many policies did nottarget drivers behind deforestati<strong>on</strong> and thus were largelyineffective. In many cases, this was due to insufficientc<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> of how to target lands under real threatof deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Interventi<strong>on</strong>s also failed due to limitedlocal engagement and insufficient stakeholder participati<strong>on</strong>,while weak governance, corrupti<strong>on</strong>, and lack ofland titles and law enforcement created further barriersto significant land-use change. In additi<strong>on</strong>, previous programsalmost universally lacked self-evaluati<strong>on</strong> mechanisms,which limited learning and thus modificati<strong>on</strong>.However as we have discussed above, many features ofpast policies could be drastically improved up<strong>on</strong> in thefuture.Designing <str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> for <strong>REDD</strong> Feasibility<strong>The</strong> prospect of rewards for internati<strong>on</strong>al forest carb<strong>on</strong>c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> under future U.S. and internati<strong>on</strong>al climatepolicies has brought new energy to the pursuit of protecti<strong>on</strong>of tropical forests. Yet the debate has not beeninformed by close c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> of the nature of theinternati<strong>on</strong>al and domestic policies required if <strong>REDD</strong> isto play a significant role. We believe that internati<strong>on</strong>aland domestic interventi<strong>on</strong>s can lower deforestati<strong>on</strong> withboth the support of local actors and smart policy design.Past failures suggest there are potential benefits fromprogram requirements that are broad enough to encouragelocally appropriate interventi<strong>on</strong>s. For instance, ifcomprehensive m<strong>on</strong>itoring captures GHG emissi<strong>on</strong>sreducti<strong>on</strong>s, then requirements and incentives can bebased <strong>on</strong> that aggregate outcome and many other detailsmay be left to local actors better placed to significantlyand sustainably shift relevant local processes. This avoidsdifficulty in m<strong>on</strong>itoring and rewarding local process.Generally, c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with those affected by these policiescan aid in the development of effective and sustainablepolicy.Such policies may not immediately come to pass, andeven if the above describes future internati<strong>on</strong>al regimesaccurately, still domestic actors will have to decide howto try to lower GHG emissi<strong>on</strong>s in order to capture forestincentive payments. For these reas<strong>on</strong>s, there is value inlearning further from both the successes and the failuresof the many previous types of forest interventi<strong>on</strong>. Drawingfrom all the above, for instance: we can ask skepticallywhether loan c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ality is likely to work withoutchanged local practices; we can str<strong>on</strong>gly encouragebringing the locally forest-dependent peoples into discussi<strong>on</strong>s;we can shift protected areas and ecopaymentstowards areas of higher forest threat and impact; and wecan evaluate whether carb<strong>on</strong>-based payments may justify,in local development terms al<strong>on</strong>e, shifts in roads orin subsidies.Nicholas Institute42


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesMoving forward:• the U.S., in c<strong>on</strong>cert with internati<strong>on</strong>al actors, canhelp forested countries with the costs of c<strong>on</strong>servingforest carb<strong>on</strong>, including with costs of strengtheningthe relevant instituti<strong>on</strong>s• internati<strong>on</strong>al forest carb<strong>on</strong> policies can adoptperformance indicators so that incentives can beeffectively applied; m<strong>on</strong>itoring and evaluati<strong>on</strong> willpermit <strong>on</strong>going learning• forested countries can rethink not <strong>on</strong>ly forestpolicy but also how agriculture and infrastructurepolicies affect forests; strategies will differ as afuncti<strong>on</strong> of local c<strong>on</strong>text• internati<strong>on</strong>al and domestic actors can re-examinewhether acti<strong>on</strong>s work well in c<strong>on</strong>cert, e.g., policyinfluences <strong>on</strong> commodity demands vs. subsidiesfor agriculture or biofuelsIn summary, it is possible to identify key deforestati<strong>on</strong>drivers and to align local, regi<strong>on</strong>al, nati<strong>on</strong>al, and internati<strong>on</strong>alincentives in many settings. Climate protecti<strong>on</strong>provides a new way for forest protecti<strong>on</strong> to c<strong>on</strong>tributeand to succeed if we learn less<strong>on</strong>s from the past.Nicholas Institute43


ReferencesAbadie, A., and G. Imbens. 2006. Large sample propertiesof matching estimators for average treatment effects.Ec<strong>on</strong>ometrica 74: 235–267.Adeney J.M., N.L. Christensen, Jr., and S.L. Pimm.2009. Reserves protect against deforestati<strong>on</strong> fires inthe Amaz<strong>on</strong>. PLoS ONE 4(4): e5014. http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.p<strong>on</strong>e.0005014.Agarwal, B. 2009. Gender and forest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>: <strong>The</strong>impact of women’s participati<strong>on</strong> in community forestgovernance. Ecological Ec<strong>on</strong>omics. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolec<strong>on</strong>.2009.04.025.Agrawal, A. 2001. <strong>The</strong> regulatory community:Decentralizati<strong>on</strong> and the envir<strong>on</strong>ment in the VanPanchayats (forest councils) of Kuma<strong>on</strong>, India.Mountain Research and Development 21(3): 208–211.Albers, H. 1996. Modeling ecological c<strong>on</strong>straints <strong>on</strong>tropical forest management: Spatial interdependence,irreversibility and uncertainty. Journal ofEnvir<strong>on</strong>mental Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Management 30: 73–94.Alix-Garcia, A. De Janvry, and E. Sadoulet. 2004. A tale oftwo communities: Explaining deforestati<strong>on</strong> in Mexico.World Development 33(2): 219–235.Alix-Garcia, J. 2007. A spatial analysis of comm<strong>on</strong>property deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Journal of Envir<strong>on</strong>mentalEc<strong>on</strong>omics and Management 53: 1241–157.Alst<strong>on</strong>, L., G. Libecap, and B. Mueller. 2000. Landreform policies, the sources of violent c<strong>on</strong>flict, andimplicati<strong>on</strong>s for deforestati<strong>on</strong> in the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>.Journal of Envir<strong>on</strong>mental Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Management39: 162–188.Alst<strong>on</strong>, L.J., G.D. Libecap, and R. Schneider. 1995.Property Rights and the Prec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for Markets: <strong>The</strong>Case of the Amaz<strong>on</strong> Fr<strong>on</strong>tier. Journal of Instituti<strong>on</strong>aland <strong>The</strong>oretical Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 151: 89–107.Amacher, G., and W. Hyde. 1996. Migrati<strong>on</strong> and theenvir<strong>on</strong>ment: <strong>The</strong> case of Philippine uplands. Journal ofPhilippine Development 42(2).Amacher, G., E. Koskela, and M. Ollikainen. 2007. Royaltyreform and illegal reporting of harvest volumes underalternative penalty schemes. Envir<strong>on</strong>mental andResource Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 8(2): 189–211.Amacher, G., E. Koskela, and M. Ollikainen. 2008.Deforestati<strong>on</strong> and property rights risks. Envir<strong>on</strong>mentand Development Ec<strong>on</strong>omics (In Press).Amacher, G., M. Ollikainen, and E. Koskela. 2008.Corrupti<strong>on</strong> and forest c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s. Paper presentedat meetings of the European Associati<strong>on</strong> ofEnvir<strong>on</strong>mental and Resource Ec<strong>on</strong>omists, Gothenburg,Sweden.Amacher, G., W. Cruz, D. Grebner, and W. Hyde. 1998.Envir<strong>on</strong>mental motivati<strong>on</strong>s for migrati<strong>on</strong>: Populati<strong>on</strong>pressure, poverty, and deforestati<strong>on</strong> in the Philippines.Land Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 74: 92–101.Amacher, G. 1999. Government preferences and publicforest harvesting: A sec<strong>on</strong>d best approach. AmericanJournal of Agricultural Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 81(1): 14–28.Andam, K., P. Ferraro, A. Pfaff, J. Robalino and A.Sanchez. 2008. Measuring the effectiveness ofprotected-area networks in reducing deforestati<strong>on</strong>.PNAS 105(42): 16089–16094.Andersen, L.E., C.W.J. Granger, E.J. Reis, D. Weinhold,and S. Wunder. 2002. <strong>The</strong> dynamics of deforestati<strong>on</strong> andec<strong>on</strong>omic growth in the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>. CambridgeUniversity Press.Anderss<strong>on</strong>, K.P., and F. Lehoucq. 2006. Municipalpolitics and forest governance: Comparative analysisof decentralizati<strong>on</strong> in Bolivia and Guatemala. WorldDevelopment 34(3): 576–595.Angelsen, A., and D. Kaimowitz. 1999. Rethinking thecauses of deforestati<strong>on</strong>: Less<strong>on</strong>s from ec<strong>on</strong>omicmodels. World Bank Research Observer 14: 73–98.Angelsen, A. 1999. Agricultural expansi<strong>on</strong> anddeforestati<strong>on</strong>: Modeling the impact of populati<strong>on</strong>,market forces, and property rights. Journal ofDevelopment Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 58: 185–218.AP (<strong>The</strong> Associated Press). 2008. Amaz<strong>on</strong> forest gets helpagainst illegal farms. March 31. http://www.msnbc.msn.com/id/23885816.Applegate, G.; F. E. Putz; L. K. Snook. 2004. WhoPays for and who benefits from improved timberharvesting practices in the tropics? Less<strong>on</strong>s learnedand informati<strong>on</strong> gaps. Bogor, Ind<strong>on</strong>esia: Center forInternati<strong>on</strong>al Forestry Research (CIFOR).Arima, E., P. Barreto, and M. Brito. 2005. Pecuária naAmazônia: Tendência e implicações para a c<strong>on</strong>servaçãoambiental. Belém, Brazil: Instituto do Homem e MeioAmbiente da Amazônia (Imaz<strong>on</strong>).Armsberg, J. 1998. Ec<strong>on</strong>omic parameters of deforestati<strong>on</strong>.World Bank Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 12: 133–153.Arnold, J., G. Kohlin, and R. Perss<strong>on</strong>. 2006. Woodfuels,livelihoods, and policy interventi<strong>on</strong>s: Changingperspectives. World Development 34: 596–611.Arriagada, Rodrigo Ant<strong>on</strong>io. 2008. Private provisi<strong>on</strong> ofpublic goods: Applying matching methods to evaluatepayments for ecosystem services in Costa Rica. PhDdissertati<strong>on</strong>. Raleigh, NC: North Carolina StateUniversity.Asner, Gregory P., et al. 2005. Selective logging in theBrazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>. Science 310: 480–481.Bacha, C.J.C. 2003. <strong>The</strong> evoluti<strong>on</strong> of wood-basedindustries in Brazil and their means of securing wood.Nicholas Institute44


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesOxford Development Studies 31(2): 197–217.Balogun, P. 2005. Evaluating progress towardsharm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong>. Working Paper 15. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: UKDepartment for Internati<strong>on</strong>al Development (DFID).Barbier, E., and J. Burgess. 1996. Ec<strong>on</strong>omic analysis ofdeforestati<strong>on</strong> in Mexico. Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and DevelopmentEc<strong>on</strong>omics 1: 203–239.Barbier, E., and J. Burgess. 1997. <strong>The</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omics of tropicalforest land use opti<strong>on</strong>s. Land Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 73: 174–95.Barbier, E., and J. Burgess. 2001a. <strong>The</strong> dynamics of tropicaldeforestati<strong>on</strong>. Journal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Surveys 15: 413–433.Barbier, E., and J. Burgess. 2001b. Tropical deforestati<strong>on</strong>,tenure insecurity and unsustain0ability. Forest Science47: 497–509.Barbier, E., R. Damania, and D. Le<strong>on</strong>ard. 2005.Corrupti<strong>on</strong>, trade and resource c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong>. Journal ofEnvir<strong>on</strong>mental Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Management 50 (2005):276–299.Barnes, D.F., K. Krutilla, and W. Hyde. 2002. <strong>The</strong>urban energy transiti<strong>on</strong>: Energy, poverty andthe envir<strong>on</strong>ment in the developing world (draft).Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: World Bank.Barr, C., I.A.P. Resosudarmo, A. Dermawan, J.McCarthy, M. Moeli<strong>on</strong>o, and B. Seti<strong>on</strong>o, eds. 2006.Decentralizati<strong>on</strong> of forest administrati<strong>on</strong> in Ind<strong>on</strong>esia:Implicati<strong>on</strong>s for forest sustainability, ec<strong>on</strong>omicdevelopment and community livelihoods. Bogor,Ind<strong>on</strong>esia: CIFOR.Barr, C. 2001. Timber c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong> reform: Questi<strong>on</strong>ing thesustainable logging paradigm. Chapter 4 in Banking <strong>on</strong>sustainability: Structural adjustment and policy reformin post-Suharto Ind<strong>on</strong>esia. Bogor, Ind<strong>on</strong>esia: CIFOR.Barreto, P. 2008. Quem é d<strong>on</strong>o da Amazônia? Uma análisedo recadastramento de imóveis rurais. Belém, Brazil:Imaz<strong>on</strong>.Barrett, C. 1999. Stochastic food prices and slash-andburnagriculture. Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and DevelopmentEc<strong>on</strong>omics 4(2): 161–176.Bass, S., and S. Guéneau. 2007. Global forest governance:Effectiveness, fairness and legitimacy of market-drivenapproaches. In Participati<strong>on</strong> for sustainability in trade,ed. S. Thoyer and B. Martimort-Asso. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Ashgate.Basu, K., S. Bhattacharya, and A. Mishra. 1992. Notes <strong>on</strong>bribery and the c<strong>on</strong>trol of corrupti<strong>on</strong>. Journal of PublicEc<strong>on</strong>omics 48: 349–359.Benhin, J. 2006. Agriculture and deforestati<strong>on</strong> in thetropics: A critical theoretical and empirical review.Ambio 35(1): 9–16.Bhattarai, M, and M. Hammig. 2001. Instituti<strong>on</strong>s andthe envir<strong>on</strong>mental Kuznets curve for deforestati<strong>on</strong>: Across-country analysis for Latin America, Africa andAsia. World Development 29(6): 995–1010.Bigsten, A. 2006. D<strong>on</strong>or coordinati<strong>on</strong> and the uses of aid.Working Papers in Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, nr 19. Gothenburg,Sweden: Göteborg University School of Business,Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Law. ISSN: 1403-2465. http://hdl.handle.net/2077/2723.Bilsborrow, R. 2002: Migrati<strong>on</strong>, populati<strong>on</strong> change, andthe rural envir<strong>on</strong>ment. Populati<strong>on</strong>, Envir<strong>on</strong>mentalChange, and Security Working Paper 2. Ann Arbor, MI,and Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: Populati<strong>on</strong> and Envir<strong>on</strong>mentFellows Program, University of Michigan andWoodrow Wils<strong>on</strong> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Center.Bitzer, V., M. Francken, and P. Glasbergen. 2008.Intersectoral partnerships for a sustainable coffeechain: Really addressing sustainability or just picking(coffee) cherries? Global Envir<strong>on</strong>mental Change 18(2):271–284.Blaser, J., and J. Douglas. 2000. A future for forests? Issuesand implicati<strong>on</strong>s for the emerging forest policy andstrategy of the World Bank. ITTO Tropical ForestUpdate 10: 9–14.Bohn, H., and R. Deac<strong>on</strong>. 2000. Ownership risk,investment, and the use of natural resources. AmericanEc<strong>on</strong>omic Review 90: 526–549.Boltz, F., D.R. Carter, T.P. Holmes, and R. Pereira, Jr. 2001.Financial returns under uncertainty for c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>aland reduced-impact logging in permanent producti<strong>on</strong>forests of the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>. Ecological Ec<strong>on</strong>omics39: 387-398.Bo<strong>on</strong>e, P. 1995. Politics and the effectiveness of foreignaid. Paper No. 272. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Center for Ec<strong>on</strong>omicPerformance, L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong> School of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics andPolitical Science.Boscolo, M., and J.R. Vincent. 2000. Promoting betterlogging practices in tropical forests: A simulati<strong>on</strong>analysis of alternative regulati<strong>on</strong>s. Land Ec<strong>on</strong>omics76(1): 1–14.Boscolo, M., and J.R. Vincent. 2007. Area fees and loggingin tropical timber c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s. Envir<strong>on</strong>ment andDevelopment Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 12: 505–520.Brandão Jr., A.O., and C.M. Souza Jr. 2006. Mappingunofficial roads with Landsat images: A new tool toimprove the m<strong>on</strong>itoring of the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>rainforest. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Journal of Remote Sensing 27:177–189.Brito, B., and P. Barreto. 2009. <strong>The</strong> risks and the principlesfor landholding regularizati<strong>on</strong> in the Amaz<strong>on</strong>. State ofthe Amaz<strong>on</strong> 10. Belém, Brazil: Imaz<strong>on</strong>.Brockett, C.D., and R.R. Gottfried. 2002. State policiesand the preservati<strong>on</strong> of forest cover. Latin AmericanResearch Review 37(1): 7–40.Bruner, A., et al. 2001. Effectiveness of parks in protectingtropical biodiversity. Science 291: 125–128.Capistrano, D. 2008. Decentralisati<strong>on</strong> and forestgovernance in Asia and the Pacific: Trends, less<strong>on</strong>sand c<strong>on</strong>tinuing challenges. In Less<strong>on</strong>s from forestNicholas Institute45


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativesdecentralisati<strong>on</strong>: M<strong>on</strong>ey, justice and the quest for goodgovernance in Asia Pacific, ed. C. Colfer, G.R. Dahaland D. Capistrano. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Earthscan.Carr, D., W. Pan, and R. Bilsborrow. 2006. Decliningfertility <strong>on</strong> the fr<strong>on</strong>tier: <strong>The</strong> Ecuadorian Amaz<strong>on</strong>.Populati<strong>on</strong> and Envir<strong>on</strong>ment 28(1): 17–39. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11111-007-0032-y.Carr, D. 2004. Proximate populati<strong>on</strong> factors anddeforestati<strong>on</strong> in tropical agricultural fr<strong>on</strong>tiers.Populati<strong>on</strong> and Envir<strong>on</strong>ment 25(6): 585–612.Cashore, B., F. Gale, E. Meidinger, and D. Newsom.2006a. C<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>ting sustainability: Forest certificati<strong>on</strong> indeveloping and transiti<strong>on</strong>ing countries. New Haven: YaleF&ES Publicati<strong>on</strong> Series.Cattaneo, A. 2001. Deforestati<strong>on</strong> in the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>:Comparing the impacts of macroec<strong>on</strong>omic shocks,land tenure and technological change. Land Ec<strong>on</strong>omics77(2): 219–240.Caviglia-Harris, Jill L., et al. 2009. Modeling land useand land cover change in an Amaz<strong>on</strong>ian fr<strong>on</strong>tiersettlement: Strategies for addressing populati<strong>on</strong> changeand panel attriti<strong>on</strong>. Journal of Land Use Science 4(4):275–307.Cerutti, P.O., and L. Tacc<strong>on</strong>i. 2008. Forests, illegality, andlivelihoods: <strong>The</strong> case of Camero<strong>on</strong>. Society & NaturalResources 21(9): 845–853.Cerutti, P. O., R. Nasi, and L. Tacc<strong>on</strong>i. 2008. Sustainableforest management in Camero<strong>on</strong> needs more thanapproved forest management plans. Ecology and Society13(2): 36. http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol13/iss2/art36.Chhatre, Ashwini, and Arun Agrawal. 2008. Forestcomm<strong>on</strong>s and local enforcement. PNAS 105(36):13286–13291.Chhatre, Ashwini, and Arun Agrawal. 2009. Trade-offsand synergies between carb<strong>on</strong> storage and livelihoodbenefits from forest comm<strong>on</strong>s. PNAS 106(42): 17667–17670.Chomitz, K., and D. Gray. 1996. Roads, land use, anddeforestati<strong>on</strong>: A spatial model applied to Belize. WorldBank Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 10: 487–512.Chomitz, K.M., and T.S. Thomas. 2003. Determinants ofland use in Amaz<strong>on</strong>ia: A fine-scale spatial analysis.American Journal of Agricultural Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 85: 1016.Chomitz, K.M. 2006. At loggerheads? Agriculturalexpansi<strong>on</strong>, poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>, and envir<strong>on</strong>ment in thetropical forests. World Bank <str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> Research Report.Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: World Bank.Clarke, H.R., W.J. Reed, and R.M. Shestra. 1993. Optimalenforcement of property rights <strong>on</strong> developing countryforests subject to illegal logging. Resource and EnergyEc<strong>on</strong>omics 15: 271–293.Claws<strong>on</strong>, M. 1979. Forests in the l<strong>on</strong>g sweep of AmericanHistory. Science 204 (4398): 1168–1174.Colfer, C., G.R. Dahal, and D. Capistrano, eds. 2008.Less<strong>on</strong>s from forest decentralizati<strong>on</strong>: M<strong>on</strong>ey, justice andthe quest for good governance in Asia-Pacific. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>:Earthscan.C<strong>on</strong>de, D.A., et al. 2010. Sex matters: Modeling maleand female habitat differences in jaguar c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>.Biological C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>. In press.C<strong>on</strong>treras-Hermosilla, A. 2000. <strong>The</strong> underlying causesof forest decline. CIFOR Occasi<strong>on</strong>al Paper #30. June.Bogor, Ind<strong>on</strong>esia: CIFOR.C<strong>on</strong>treras-Hermosilla, A. 2002. Law compliance in theforestry sector: An overview. World Bank Institute.Cooke, P., G. Kohlin, and W. Hyde. 2008. Fuelwood,forests, and community management: Evidence fromhousehold studies. Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and DevelopmentEc<strong>on</strong>omics 13: 103–135.Cooke, P. A. 1998. Intrahousehold labor allocati<strong>on</strong>resp<strong>on</strong>ses to envir<strong>on</strong>mental good scarcity. Ec<strong>on</strong>omicDevelopment and Cultural Change 46(4): 807–830.Cooke St. Clair, P., Hyde, W.F., and Kohlin, G. 2001. Afuelwood crisis: Where and for whom? In Fuelwood—Crisis or balance: Workshop proceedings, G. Kohlin,ed., Marstrand, June 6–9, 2001 (18–53). Gothenburg,Sweden: Göteborg University for CIFOR.Cooper, C. 2008. Welfare effects of community forestmanagement: Evidence from the rural hills ofNepal. PhD dissertati<strong>on</strong>, Department of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics,University of Southern California.Cotula, L., C. Toulmin, and C. Hesse. 2004. Land tenureand administrati<strong>on</strong> in Africa: Less<strong>on</strong>s of experienceand emerging issues. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Internati<strong>on</strong>al Institutefor Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and Development (IIED). http://www.iied.org/pubs/pdfs/9305IIED.pdf.Cropper M, Puri J, Griffiths C. 2001. Predicting thelocati<strong>on</strong> of deforestati<strong>on</strong>: <strong>The</strong> role of roads andprotected areas in North Thailand. Land Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 77:172–186.Curran, L.M., et al. 2004. Lowland forest loss in protectedareas of Ind<strong>on</strong>esian Borneo. Science 303: 1000–1003.Dahal, G.R., and K.P. Adhikari. 2008. Trends and impactof forest tenure reforms in Asia. Journal of Forest andLivelihood 7(1): 19–26.Daviet, F. 2009. Legally <strong>REDD</strong>: Building readiness for<strong>REDD</strong> by supporting developing countries in thefight against illegal logging. WRI Working Paper.Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: World Resources Institute.Deac<strong>on</strong>, R., and P. Murphy. 1997. <strong>The</strong> structure of anenvir<strong>on</strong>mental transacti<strong>on</strong>: <strong>The</strong> debt-for-nature swap.Land Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 73(1): 1–24. http://www.jstor.org/stable/3147074.De Camino, R., O. Segura, L.G. Arias, and I. Pérez. 2000.Costa Rica: Forest strategy and the evoluti<strong>on</strong> of landuse. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: World Bank.Nicholas Institute46


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesDeFries, R., et al. 2005. Increasing isolati<strong>on</strong> of protectedareas in tropical forests over the past twenty years.Ecological Applicati<strong>on</strong>s 15(1): 19–26.Delacote, P. 2008. Systemic corrupti<strong>on</strong>, scale effectsand forest harvesting. Working paper, Laboratoired’Ec<strong>on</strong>omie Forestière – INRA.Delacote, P. 2009. On the sources of c<strong>on</strong>sumer boycottsineffectiveness. Journal of Envir<strong>on</strong>ment & Development18(3): 306–322.Delgado, C., D.A. C<strong>on</strong>de, J.O. Sext<strong>on</strong>, F. Colchero, J.J.Swensen, and A. Pfaff. 2010. Deforestati<strong>on</strong> dynamics inresp<strong>on</strong>se to the evoluti<strong>on</strong> of the Western Amaz<strong>on</strong>ianInter-Oceanic Highway. Duke University mimeo(submitted).Delgado, C., et al. 2008. Presentati<strong>on</strong> at the NASA LBAc<strong>on</strong>ference Amaz<strong>on</strong> in Perspective, Manaus, Brazil.Departemen Kehutanan. 2009. List of applicati<strong>on</strong>s forIUPHHK-RE. http://phapl.dephut.net/CMS_PHAPL/news.aspx?NewsId=46.Dietz, T., E. Ostrom, and P.C. Stern. 2003. <strong>The</strong> struggle togovern the comm<strong>on</strong>s. Science 302: 1907–1912.Easterly, W. 2007. Are aid agencies improving? Ec<strong>on</strong>omic<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> 22(52): 633–678.Edm<strong>on</strong>ds, E.V. 2002. Government-initiated communityresource management and local resource extracti<strong>on</strong>from Nepal’s forests. Journal of Development Ec<strong>on</strong>omics68(1): 89–115.Engel, S., and C. Palmer. 2008. Payments forenvir<strong>on</strong>mental services as an alternative to loggingunder weak property rights: <strong>The</strong> case of Ind<strong>on</strong>esia.Ecological Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 65: 799–809.EUROPA. 2009. Development and Relati<strong>on</strong>s with African,Caribbean, and Pacific States. http://ec.europa.eu/development/policies/9interventi<strong>on</strong>areas/envir<strong>on</strong>ment/forest/forestry_intro_en.cfm.Ewers, R., J. Scharlemann, A. Balmford, and R. Green.2009. Do increases in agricultural yield spare land fornature? Global Change Biology 15(7): 1716–1726.FAO (Food and Agricultural Organizati<strong>on</strong>). 1989. Basicprinciples of the TFAP. Rome: FAO.FAO. 1991. 1990 global forest resources assessment. Rome:FAO.FAO. 2005. State of the world’s forests. Rome: FAO.Fargi<strong>on</strong>e, J., J. Hill, D. Tilman, S. Polasky, and P.Hawthorne. 2008. Land clearing and the biofuel carb<strong>on</strong>debt. Science 319: 1235–1237.Fearnside, P.M. 2001. Land-tenure issues as factors inenvir<strong>on</strong>mental destructi<strong>on</strong> in the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>ia:<strong>The</strong> case of southern Pará. World Development 29:1361–1372.Fearnside, P.M. 2005a. C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> policy in BrazilianAmaz<strong>on</strong>ia: Understanding the dilemmas. WorldDevelopment 31(5): 757–779.Fearnside, P.M. 2005b. Indigenous peoples as providers ofenvir<strong>on</strong>mental services in Amaz<strong>on</strong>ia: Warning signsfrom Mato Grosso. In Global impact, local acti<strong>on</strong>: Newenvir<strong>on</strong>mental policy in Latin America, ed. A. Hall.L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: University of L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>, School of AdvancedStudies, Institute for the Study of the Americas.Fearnside, P.M. 2005c. Deforestati<strong>on</strong> in BrazilianAmaz<strong>on</strong>ia: History, rates, and c<strong>on</strong>sequences.C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> Biology 19: 680–688Ferreira, S., and J. Vincent. 2010 (in press). Governanceand timber harvests. Envir<strong>on</strong>mental and ResourceEc<strong>on</strong>omics.Finer, M., C.N. Jenkins, S.L. Pimm, B. Keane, and C. Ross.2008. Oil and gas projects in the western Amaz<strong>on</strong>:Threats to wilderness, biodiversity, and indigenouspeoples. PLoS ONE 3(8): e2932. http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.p<strong>on</strong>e.0002932.Fitzherbert, E.B., et al. 2008. How will oil palmexpansi<strong>on</strong> affect biodiversity? Trends in Ecology andEvoluti<strong>on</strong> 23(10): 538–545.FLEGT (Forest Law Enforcement, Governance andTrade). Briefing Note #6.Foster, A., and M. Rosenzweig. 2003. Ec<strong>on</strong>omic growthand the rise of forests. Quarterly Journal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics118(2): 601–637.Fox, J., R.R. Rindfuss, S.J. Walsh, and V. Mishra, eds. 2003.People and the envir<strong>on</strong>ment: Approaches for linkinghousehold and community surveys to remote sensingand GIS. Dordrecht, Netherlands: Kluwer AcademicPublishing Group.FSC (Forest Stewardship Council). 2009. ForestStewardship Council facts and figures. Accessed 1 May2010. http://www.fsc.org/facts-figures.html.Fujisaka, S., W. Bell, N. Thomas, L. Hurtado, and E.Crawford. 1996. Slash-and-burn agriculture c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong>to pasture and deforestati<strong>on</strong> in two Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>col<strong>on</strong>ies. Agriculture, Ecosystems & Envir<strong>on</strong>ment 59:115–130.Fuller, D., T. Jessup, and A. Salim. 2004. Loss of forestcover in Kalimantan, Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, since the 1997–1998El Niño. C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> Biology 18: 249–254.Gaveau, D.L.A., H. Wand<strong>on</strong>o, and F. Setiabudi. 2007.Three decades of deforestati<strong>on</strong> in southwest Sumatra:Have protected areas halted forest loss and logging,and promoted re-growth? Biological C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> 134:495–504.Geist, H.J., and E.F. Lambin. 2001. What drives tropicaldeforestati<strong>on</strong>? A meta-analysis of proximateand underlying causes of deforestati<strong>on</strong> based <strong>on</strong>subnati<strong>on</strong>al case study evidence. LUCC Report Series,No. 4. Louvain, Belgium: LUCC Internati<strong>on</strong>al ProjectOffice, University of Louvain.Geist, H.J., and E.F. Lambin. 2002. Proximate causes andunderlying driving forces of tropical deforestati<strong>on</strong>.Nicholas Institute47


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesBioScience 52(2): 143–150.Gibbs, H.K., et al. 2008. Carb<strong>on</strong> payback times for cropbasedbiofuel expansi<strong>on</strong> in the tropics: <strong>The</strong> effects ofchanging yield and technology. Envir<strong>on</strong>mental ResearchLetters 3(2008). http://dx.doi.org/10.1088/1748-9326/3/3/034001.Gray, J. 2002. Forest c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong> policies and revenuesystems: Country experience and policy changes forsustainable tropical forestry. World Bank TechnicalPaper, Forest Series, Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.Grossman, G., and A. Krueger. 1995. Ec<strong>on</strong>omic growthand the envir<strong>on</strong>ment. Quarterly Journal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics110(2): 353–377.Guertin, C. 2003. Illegal logging and illegal activities inthe forest sector: Overview and possible issues forthe UNECE timber committee and FAO EuropeanForestry Commissi<strong>on</strong>. Presented at UNECE TimberCommittee Market Discussi<strong>on</strong>s, October 7–8, 2003,Geneva, Switzerland.Hall<strong>on</strong>en-Akatwijuka, M. 2004. Coordinati<strong>on</strong> failure inforeign aid. Department of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, University ofBristol, mimeo.Hardner, J., and R. Rice. 2000. Rethinking forest usec<strong>on</strong>tracts in Latin America. Envir<strong>on</strong>ment Divisi<strong>on</strong> WP.Interamerican Development Bank, Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.Hecht, S. 2005. Soybeans, development and c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> the Amaz<strong>on</strong> Fr<strong>on</strong>tier. Development and Change36(2): 375–404.Hecht, S.B. 1993. <strong>The</strong> logic of livestock and deforestati<strong>on</strong>in Amaz<strong>on</strong>ia. BioScience 43(10): 687–696.Hofstad, O. 1997. Woodland deforestati<strong>on</strong> by charcoalsupply to Dar es Salaam. Journal of Envir<strong>on</strong>mentalEc<strong>on</strong>omics and Management 33: 17–32.Homma, A.K.O., R.N.B. Alves, A.J.E. Amorim deMenezes, and G.B. de Matos. 2006. Guseiras naAmazônia: Perigo para a floresta. Ciência Hoje 39(233):56–59.H<strong>on</strong>ey-Rosés, J. 2009. Illegal logging in comm<strong>on</strong> propertyforests. Society & Natural Resources 22(10): 916–930.Hotte, L. 2005. Natural-resource exploitati<strong>on</strong> with costlyenforcement of property rights. Oxford Ec<strong>on</strong>omicPapers 57: 497–521.Human Rights Watch. 2009. Wild m<strong>on</strong>ey: <strong>The</strong> humanrights c<strong>on</strong>sequences of illegal logging and corrupti<strong>on</strong>in Ind<strong>on</strong>esia’s forestry sector. New York, NY: HumanRights Watch.Humphreys, David. 1996. <strong>The</strong> Tropical Forestry Acti<strong>on</strong>Programme. Chapter 2 in Forest politics: <strong>The</strong> evoluti<strong>on</strong>of internati<strong>on</strong>al cooperati<strong>on</strong>. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Earthscan.Hyde, W., and G. Amacher. 2001, eds. Ec<strong>on</strong>omicsof forestry development in Asia: An empiricalintroducti<strong>on</strong>. Ann Arbor, MI: University of MichiganPress.Hyde, W., and R Sedjo. 1992. Managing tropical forests:Reflecti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> the rent distributi<strong>on</strong> discussi<strong>on</strong>. LandEc<strong>on</strong>omics 68(3): 43–50.Hyde, W., G. Amacher, and W. Magrath. 1996.Deforestati<strong>on</strong>, scarce forest resources, and forestland use: <strong>The</strong>ory, empirical evidence, and policyimplicati<strong>on</strong>s. World Bank Research Observer 11(2):223–248.INPE (Instituto Naci<strong>on</strong>al de Pesquisas Espaciais). 2008.M<strong>on</strong>itoramento da floresta Amazônica Brasileira porsatélite – Projeto prodes. http://www.obt.inpe.br/prodes/prodes_1988_2007.htm.Internati<strong>on</strong>al Tropical Trade Organizati<strong>on</strong> (ITTO). 2005.Status of tropical forest management: Summary report,a special editi<strong>on</strong> of the Tropical Forest Update. ITTOTropical Forest Update 16: 2006.Jain A.K. 2001. Corrupti<strong>on</strong>: A review. Journal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omicSurveys, 15(1): 71–121.Jenkins, M. 2008. Who murdered the Virunga gorillas?Nati<strong>on</strong>al Geographic July: 34–65.Johannes Ebeling and Maï Yasué. <strong>The</strong> effectiveness ofmarket-based c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> in the tropics: Forestcertificati<strong>on</strong> in Ecuador and Bolivia. Journal ofEnvir<strong>on</strong>mental Management 90(2): 1145–1153.Joppa, L., and A. Pfaff. 2009. High and far: Biases in thelocati<strong>on</strong> of protected areas. PLoS ONE 4(12): e8273.http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.p<strong>on</strong>e.0008273.Joppa, L., and A. Pfaff. 2010a. Reassessing the forestimpacts of protecti<strong>on</strong>: <strong>The</strong> challenge of n<strong>on</strong>randomprotecti<strong>on</strong> and a corrective method. Annals of the NewYork Academy of Sciences 1185: 135–149.Joppa, L., and A. Pfaff. 2010b. Global park impacts: Howcould protected areas avoid more deforestati<strong>on</strong>?Mimeo, Duke University (submitted).Jumbe, C.B.L., and A. Angelsen. Do the poor benefit fromdevoluti<strong>on</strong> policies? Evidence from Malawi’s ForestCo-Management Program. Land Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 82(4):562–581.Just, R.E., and J.A. Miranowski. 1993. Understandingfarmland price changes. American Journal ofAgricultural Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 75 (1): 156–168.Kahn, J., and J. McD<strong>on</strong>ald. 1995. Third-world debtand tropical deforestati<strong>on</strong>. Ecological Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 12:107–123.Kaimowitz, D., and A. Angelsen. 1998. Ec<strong>on</strong>omic modelsof tropical deforestati<strong>on</strong>: A review. Bogor, Ind<strong>on</strong>esia:CIFOR.Kaimowitz, D., and J. Smith. 2001. Soybean technologyand the loss of natural vegetati<strong>on</strong> in Brazil and Bolivia.Chapter 11 in Agricultural technologies and tropicaldeforestati<strong>on</strong>, ed. A. Angelsen and D. Kaimowitz. CABI.Karsenty, A. 2007. Questi<strong>on</strong>ing rent for developmentswaps: New market based instruments for biodiversityNicholas Institute48


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativesacquisiti<strong>on</strong> and the land-use issue in tropical countries.Internati<strong>on</strong>al Forestry Review 9(1): 503–513.Karsenty, A. 2008. <strong>The</strong> architecture of proposed <strong>REDD</strong>schemes after Bali: Facing critical choices. Internati<strong>on</strong>alForestry Review 10: 443–457.Keohane, R.O., and Levy, M.A., eds. 1996. Instituti<strong>on</strong>sfor envir<strong>on</strong>mental aid. Global Envir<strong>on</strong>mental AccordSeries. Cambridge, MA: Massachusetts Institute ofTechnology (MIT).Kinnaird, M.F., et al. 2003. Deforestati<strong>on</strong> trends in atropical landscape and implicati<strong>on</strong>s for endangeredlarge mammals. C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> Biology 17: 245–257.Kirby, K.R., et al. 2006. <strong>The</strong> future of deforestati<strong>on</strong> in theBrazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>. Futures 38: 432–453.Kishor, N., M. Mani, and L. C<strong>on</strong>stantino. 2008. Ec<strong>on</strong>omicand envir<strong>on</strong>mental benefits of eliminating log exportbans – <strong>The</strong> case of Costa Rica. World Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 27(4):609–624.Knack, A., and Rahman, A. 2004. D<strong>on</strong>or fragmentati<strong>on</strong>and bureaucratic quality in aid recipients. BackgroundPaper to World Development Report 2004, Washingt<strong>on</strong>,D.C.Koh, L.P., and D.S. Wilcove. 2008. Is oil palm agriculturereally destroying tropical biodiversity? C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>Letters 1(2): 60–64.Kohlin, G., and G. Amacher. 2005. Welfare implicati<strong>on</strong>sof social forestry projects: <strong>The</strong> case of Orissa India.American Journal of Agricultural Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 87(4):855–869.Kohlin, G., and P. Parks. 2001 Spatial variability andincentives to harvest: Deforestati<strong>on</strong> and fuelwoodcollecti<strong>on</strong> in South Asia. Land Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 77: 206–18.Larrea, C., and L. Warnars. 2009. Ecuador’s Yasuni-ITTinitiative: Avoiding emissi<strong>on</strong>s by keeping petroleumunderground. Energy for Sustainable Development13(3): 219–223.Lars<strong>on</strong>, A.M. 2004. Democratic decentralisati<strong>on</strong> in theforestry sector: Less<strong>on</strong>s learned from Africa, Asia andLatin America.Lars<strong>on</strong>, Anne M., and Jesse C. Ribot. 2007. <strong>The</strong> poverty offorestry policy: Double standards <strong>on</strong> an uneven playingfield. Sustainability Science 2: 189–204.Laurance, W.F., et al. 2001. <strong>The</strong> future of the BrazilianAmaz<strong>on</strong>. Science 291: 438.Laws<strong>on</strong>, S. 2005. Stemming the tide: Halting the trade instolen timber in Asia, EIA and Telepak. http://www.illegal-logging.info/uploads/reports114-1.pdf.Lentini, M., et al. 2005. Fatos Florestais da Amazônia 2005.Belém, Brazil: Imaz<strong>on</strong>.Liu, J.G., et al. 2001. Ecological degradati<strong>on</strong> in protectedareas: <strong>The</strong> case of Wol<strong>on</strong>g Nature Reserve for giantpandas. Science 292: 98–101.Lopez, R., and G. Galinato. 2005. Deforestati<strong>on</strong> and forestinducedcarb<strong>on</strong> dioxide emissi<strong>on</strong>s in tropical countries:How do governance and trade openness affect theforest-income relati<strong>on</strong>ship? Journal of Envir<strong>on</strong>ment &Development 14(1): 73–100.Lund, Jens Friis. 2007. Is small beautiful? Village-leveltaxati<strong>on</strong> of natural resources in Tanzania. PublicAdministrati<strong>on</strong> and Development 27: 307–318.Lyke, J., and S.R. Fletcher. 1992. Deforestati<strong>on</strong>: Anoverview of global programs and agreements. AC<strong>on</strong>gressi<strong>on</strong>al Research Service Report for C<strong>on</strong>gress.92-764 ENR. 21 Oct. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.MacD<strong>on</strong>ald, D., W. Adamowicz, and M. Luckert. 2001.Fuelwood collecti<strong>on</strong> in northeastern Zimbabwe:Valuati<strong>on</strong> and caloric expenditures. Journal of ForestEc<strong>on</strong>omics 7(2001): 29–51.Madeira, E.M. 2009. <strong>REDD</strong> in design assessment ofplanned first-generati<strong>on</strong> activities in Ind<strong>on</strong>esia. RFFDiscussi<strong>on</strong> Paper 09-49. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: Resourcesfor the Future.Mahar, D.A. 1989. Government policies and deforestati<strong>on</strong>in Brazil’s Amaz<strong>on</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: WorldBank.Margulis, S. 2003. Causes of deforestati<strong>on</strong> in the BrazilianAmaz<strong>on</strong>. Working Paper 22. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: WorldBank.Mayer, W., and A. Mourmouras. 2005. On the viability ofc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al assistance programs. IMF Working Paper.http://ssrn.com/abstract=887990.McKean, M.A. 2002. Comm<strong>on</strong> property and Coaseianbargains. Unpublished manuscript.Mendelsohn, R. 1994. Property rights and tropicaldeforestati<strong>on</strong>. Oxford Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Papers 46: 750–756.Merry, F., and G. Amacher. 2005. Forest c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s andpolicy choices for the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>. Journal ofSustainable Forestry 20(2): 15–44.Merry, F., G. Amacher, B. Pokorny, E. Lima, E. Scholz,and D. Nepstad. 2002. Some doubts about forestc<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s in the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>. ITTO TropicalForestry Update.Merry, F., G. Amacher, D. Nepstad, and E. Lima. 2008.Land values in fr<strong>on</strong>tier settlements of the BrazilianAmaz<strong>on</strong>. World Development (in press).Merry, F., G. Amacher, D. Nepstad, E. Lima, P. Lefebvre,and S. Bauch. 2006. Industrial development <strong>on</strong> loggingfr<strong>on</strong>tiers in the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>. Internati<strong>on</strong>alJournal of Sustainable Development 9: 277–296.Mertens, B., and E. Lambin. 2000. Land-cover-changetrajectories in southern Camero<strong>on</strong>. Annals of theAssociati<strong>on</strong> of American Geographers 90: 467–494.Mertens, B., R. Poccard-Chapuis, M.-G. Piketty, A.-E.Lacques, and A. Venturieri. 2002. Crossing spatialanalyses and livestock ec<strong>on</strong>omics to understanddeforestati<strong>on</strong> processes in the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>: <strong>The</strong>Nicholas Institute49


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativescase of São Félix do Xingu in South Pará. AgriculturalEc<strong>on</strong>omics 27: 269–294.Mertens, B., W. Sunderlin, and O. Ndoye. 2000. Impactof macroec<strong>on</strong>omic change <strong>on</strong> deforestati<strong>on</strong> in southCamero<strong>on</strong>: Integrati<strong>on</strong> of household survey andremotely-sensed data. World Development 28(6):983–999.Messina, J.P., et al. 2006. Land tenure and deforestati<strong>on</strong>patterns in the Ecuadorian Amaz<strong>on</strong>: C<strong>on</strong>flicts in landc<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> in fr<strong>on</strong>tier settings. Applied Geography 26:113–128.Miranda, M., C. Dieperink, and P. Glasbergen. 2006.Costa Rican envir<strong>on</strong>mental service payments: <strong>The</strong>use of a financial instrument in participatory forestmanagement. Envir<strong>on</strong>mental Management 38: 562–571.Miranda, M., I. Porras, and M. Moreno. 2003. <strong>The</strong> socialimpacts of payments for envir<strong>on</strong>mental services inCosta Rica. A quantitative field survey and analysis ofthe Virilla watershed. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: IIED (processed).Mishra, A. 2002. Hierarchies, incentives and collusi<strong>on</strong>.Journal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Behavior and Organizati<strong>on</strong> 47:165–178.Mishra, A. 2004. Corrupti<strong>on</strong>, hierarchies, andbureaucratic structure. Chapter 7 in Internati<strong>on</strong>alHandbook <strong>on</strong> the Ec<strong>on</strong>omics of Corrupti<strong>on</strong>, ed. S. Rose-Ackerman. Edward Elgar Press.Moelino, M., E. Wollenberg, and G. Limberg. 2008.Decentralizati<strong>on</strong> of forest governance: Politics,ec<strong>on</strong>omics and the fight for c<strong>on</strong>trol of forests inInd<strong>on</strong>esian Borneo. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Earthscan.M<strong>on</strong>gabay.com. 2009. Attacking the demand sideof deforestati<strong>on</strong>. June 16. http://news.m<strong>on</strong>gabay.com/2009/0615-forest_disclosure.html.Moran, E., E.S. Br<strong>on</strong>dizio, and S.D. McCracken. 2002.Trajectories of land use. In Deforestati<strong>on</strong> and landuse in the Amaz<strong>on</strong>, ed. C.H. Wood and R. Porro.Gainesville: University Press of Florida.Moran, Emilio. 1993. Deforestati<strong>on</strong> and land use in theBrazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>. Human Ecology 21(1): 1–21.Mort<strong>on</strong>, D.C., et al. 2006. Cropland expansi<strong>on</strong> changesdeforestati<strong>on</strong> dynamics in the southern BrazilianAmaz<strong>on</strong>. PNAS 103(39): 14637–14641.Mort<strong>on</strong>, D.C., R.S. Defries, J.T. Randers<strong>on</strong>, L. Giglio, W.Schroeder, and G.R. van der Werf. 2008. Agriculturalintensificati<strong>on</strong> increases deforestati<strong>on</strong> fire activity inAmaz<strong>on</strong>ia. Global Change Biology 14: 2262–75.Murdiyarso, D., and L. Lebel. 2007. Local to globalperspectives <strong>on</strong> forest and land fires in Southeast Asia.Mitigati<strong>on</strong> and Adaptati<strong>on</strong> Strategies for Global Change12: 3–11.Nagendra, H. 2007. Drivers of reforestati<strong>on</strong> in humandominatedforests. PNAS 104(39): 15218–15223.Nepstad, D., C. Azevedo-Ramos, E. Lima, D. McGrath,C. Pereira, and F. Merry. 2004. Managing the Amaz<strong>on</strong>timber industry. C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> Biology 18:1–3.Nepstad, D., et al. 2001. Road paving, fire regimefeedbacks, and the future of Amaz<strong>on</strong> forests. ForestEcology and Management 154: 395–407.Nepstad, D., et al. 2006b. Inhibiti<strong>on</strong> of Amaz<strong>on</strong>deforestati<strong>on</strong> and fire by parks and indigenous lands.C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> Biology 20(1): 65–73.Nepstad, D.C., C.M. Stickler, and O.T. Almeida. 2006a.Globalizati<strong>on</strong> of the Amaz<strong>on</strong> soy and beef industries:Opportunities for c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> Biology20: 1595–1603.Nepstad D., et al. <strong>The</strong> end of deforestati<strong>on</strong> in the BrazilianAmaz<strong>on</strong>. Science 326: 1350–1351OECD (Organisati<strong>on</strong> for Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Co-operati<strong>on</strong> andDevelopment). 2003. Harm<strong>on</strong>izing d<strong>on</strong>or practices foreffective aid delivery. Paris: OECD.Oksanen, T., M. Heering, B. Cabarle, and C. Sargent.1993. A study <strong>on</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong> in sustainable forestrydevelopment. Report to the Tropical Forestry Acti<strong>on</strong>Program Forestry Advisers’ Group, June.Ortiz, E., L. Sage, and C. Borge. 2003. Impacto delprograma de pago de servicios ambientales en CostaRica como medio de reducción de la pobreza en losmedios rurales. Serie de Publicaci<strong>on</strong>es RUTA. San José,Costa Rica: Unidad Regi<strong>on</strong>al de Asistencia Técnica.Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the comm<strong>on</strong>s: <strong>The</strong>evoluti<strong>on</strong> of instituti<strong>on</strong>s for collective acti<strong>on</strong>. New York:Cambridge University Press.Ostrom, Elinor. 2009. A general framework for analyzingsustainability of social-ecological systems. Science 325:419–422.Overdevest, C. 2009. Comparing forest certificati<strong>on</strong>schemes: <strong>The</strong> case of ratcheting standards in the forestsector. Socio-Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 8(1): 47–76.Oy, Indufor. 2000. Mid-term review of the pilot programto c<strong>on</strong>serve the Brazilian rain forest: Final report of theevaluatory phase.Oy<strong>on</strong>o, P.R., C. Kouna, and W. Mala. 2003. Benefits offorests in Camero<strong>on</strong>. Global structure, issues involvingaccess and decisi<strong>on</strong>-making hiccoughs. Forest <str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g>and Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 7(3): 357–368.Oy<strong>on</strong>o, P.R. 2005. Profiling local-level outcomesof envir<strong>on</strong>mental decentralizati<strong>on</strong>s: <strong>The</strong> case ofCamero<strong>on</strong>’s forests in the C<strong>on</strong>go basin. Journal ofEnvir<strong>on</strong>ment & Development 14(3): 317–337.Oy<strong>on</strong>o, R. 2004. One step forward, two steps back? Paradoxes of natural resources managementdecentralisati<strong>on</strong> in Camero<strong>on</strong>. Journal of ModernAfrican Studies 42(1): 91–111.Ozório de Almeida, Anna Luíza, and J. S. Campari. 1995.Sustainable Settlement in the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>. NewYork: Oxford University Press.Nicholas Institute50


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesO’Hare, M., R.J. Plevin, J.I. Martin, A.D. J<strong>on</strong>es, A. Kendall,and E. Hops<strong>on</strong>. 2009. Proper accounting for timeincreases crop-based biofuels’ greenhouse gas deficitversus petroleum. Envir<strong>on</strong>mental Resource Letters.http://dx.doi.org/10.1088/1748-9326/4/2/024001.Pacheco, P. 2005. Decentralizati<strong>on</strong> of forest managementin Bolivia: Who benefits and why? Chapter 9 in <strong>The</strong>politics of decentralizati<strong>on</strong>: Forests, people, and power,ed. Carol J. Pierce Colfer and Doris Capistrano.L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Earthscan.Palmer, C. 2003. <strong>The</strong> extent and causes of illegal logging:An analysis of a major cause of tropical deforestati<strong>on</strong> inInd<strong>on</strong>esia. Center for Social and Ec<strong>on</strong>omics Research,University College L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>. ISSN 0967-8875.Palmer, C.E. 2005. <strong>The</strong> Nature of Corrupti<strong>on</strong> in forestmanagement. World Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 6(2): 1–10.Partzsch, L. 2009. <strong>The</strong> legitimacy of biofuel certificati<strong>on</strong>.Agriculture and Human Values. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10460-009-9235-4.Pattanayak, S.K., and E. Sills. 2001. Do tropical forestsprovide natural insurance? N<strong>on</strong>-timber forest productcollecti<strong>on</strong> in the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>. Land Ec<strong>on</strong>omics77(4): 595–612.Perz, S.G., C. Aramburú, and J. Bremner. 2005.Populati<strong>on</strong>, land use and deforestati<strong>on</strong> in the PanAmaz<strong>on</strong> basin: A comparis<strong>on</strong> of Brazil, Bolivia,Colombia, Ecuador, Peru and Venezuela. Envir<strong>on</strong>ment,Development and Sustainability 7: 23–49.Perz, S.G., C. Overdevest, E.Y. Arima, M.M. Caldas,and R.T. Walker. 2007. Unofficial road building inthe Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>: Dilemmas and models ofroad governance. Envir<strong>on</strong>mental C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> 34(2):112–121.Pfaff, A., and J. Robalino. 2009. Evaluating deforestati<strong>on</strong>impacts of protected areas. Presented at C<strong>on</strong>nectingAmaz<strong>on</strong> Protected Areas and Indigenous Lands to<strong>REDD</strong> Frameworks, Stanford, CA.Pfaff, A., and R. Walker. 2010. Regi<strong>on</strong>al Interdependenceand Forest “Transiti<strong>on</strong>s”: Substitute deforestati<strong>on</strong> limitsthe relevance of local reversals. Land Use <str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> 27:119–129.Pfaff, A., et al. 2006. Roads and deforestati<strong>on</strong> in theBrazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>. Duke Mimeo (and revise/resubmit).Pfaff, A., et al. 2007. Road investments, spatialintensificati<strong>on</strong> and deforestati<strong>on</strong> in the BrazilianAmaz<strong>on</strong>. Journal of Regi<strong>on</strong>al Science 47: 109–123.Pfaff, A., J.A. Robalino, and G.A. Sánchez-Azofeifa.2008. Payments for envir<strong>on</strong>mental services: Empiricalanalysis for Costa Rica 1997–2000. Duke University,Sanford Working Paper.Pfaff, A., J.A. Robalino, and L.D. Herrera. 2009. <strong>REDD</strong>Roads? Spatial fr<strong>on</strong>tier dynamics and spatial variati<strong>on</strong>in causal impacts. U. of Tor<strong>on</strong>to, Urban and Real EstateEc<strong>on</strong>omics seminar, December 10, 2009.Pfaff, A., J.A. Robalino, G.A. Sánchez-Azofeifa, K. Andam,and P. Ferraro. 2009. Park locati<strong>on</strong> affects forestprotecti<strong>on</strong>: Land characteristics cause differencesin park impacts across Costa Rica. <strong>The</strong> B.E. Journalof Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Analysis & <str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> 9(2)(C<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s),Article 5. http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/vol9/iss2/art5.Pfaff, A., J.A. Robalino, S. Perz, R. Walker, et al. 2008.Development, roads and deforestati<strong>on</strong> in the BrazilianAmaz<strong>on</strong>: An empirical view across decades. LBAPresentati<strong>on</strong>.Pfaff, A. 1999. What drives deforestati<strong>on</strong> in the BrazilianAmaz<strong>on</strong>? Evidence from satellite and socioec<strong>on</strong>omicdata. Journal of Envir<strong>on</strong>mental Ec<strong>on</strong>omics andManagement 37(1): 26–43.Pfaff A., S. Chaudhuri, and H. Nye. 2004. Householdproducti<strong>on</strong> and envir<strong>on</strong>mental Kuznets curves:Examining the desirability and feasibility ofsubstituti<strong>on</strong>. Envir<strong>on</strong>mental & Resource Ec<strong>on</strong>omics27(2): 187–200.Pinard, M.A., and W.P. Cropper. 2000. Simulated effects oflogging <strong>on</strong> carb<strong>on</strong> storage in dipterocarp forest. Journalof Applied Ecology 37: 267.Purnomo, H., M. van Noordwijk, and B. Seti<strong>on</strong>o,eds. 2007. Methodology/architecture study 3:Payment mechanisms, distributi<strong>on</strong> and instituti<strong>on</strong>alarrangements. Ind<strong>on</strong>esian Forest Climate Alliance.Putz, F.E. 2005. Can tropical forests be managed fortimber producti<strong>on</strong> and wildlife protecti<strong>on</strong>. Ch. 8 inMillennium Ecosystem Assessment Vol. 3, Ecosystemsand human well-being. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: Island Press.Putz. F.E., D.O. Dykstra, and R. Heinrich. 2000. Why poorlogging practices persist in the tropics. C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>Biology 14(4): 951–956.Raynolds L.T., D. Murray, and A. Heller. 2007. Regulatingsustainability in the coffee sector: A comparativeanalysis of third-party envir<strong>on</strong>mental and socialcertificati<strong>on</strong> initiatives. Agriculture and Human Values24: 147–63Reis, E.J., and R. Guzman. 1992. An ec<strong>on</strong>ometric model ofAmaz<strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>. IPEA/Rio Working Papers.Reis, E. J., and S. Margulis. 1994. An ec<strong>on</strong>ometric modelof Amaz<strong>on</strong> deforestati<strong>on</strong>. In <strong>The</strong> causes of tropicaldeforestati<strong>on</strong>: <strong>The</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic and statistical analysis offactors giving rise to the loss of tropical forests, ed. K.Brown and D. W. Pearce. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: University CollegeL<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong> Press.Resor, J.P. 1997. Debt-for-nature swaps: A decade ofexperience and new directi<strong>on</strong>s for the future. FAO.http://www.fao.org/docrep/w3247e/w3247e06.htm.Resosudarmo, I.A.P. 2004. Closer to people and trees: Willdecentralisati<strong>on</strong> work for the people and the forests ofInd<strong>on</strong>esia? European Journal of Development Research16(1): 110–132.Nicholas Institute51


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesRhodes, W.M., E.P. Allen, and M. Callahan. 2006. Illegallogging: A market-based analysis of traffickingin illegal timber. Final report submitted to U.S.Department of Justice.Ribot, Jesse. 2002. Democratic decentralizati<strong>on</strong> of naturalresources: Instituti<strong>on</strong>alizing popular participati<strong>on</strong>.Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: World Resources Institute.Ribot, Jesse C., and Anne M. Lars<strong>on</strong>. 2005. Democraticdecentralisati<strong>on</strong> through a natural resource lens. NewYork: Routledge.Richards, M. 1995. Role of demand side incentives in finegrained protecti<strong>on</strong>: A case study of Ghana’s tropicalhigh forest. Forest Ecology and Management 78 (1995)225–241.Richards, R. 1999. Internalizing the externalities oftropical forestry: Review of financing and incentivemechanisms. Overseas Development Institute, L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>.Robalino, J., A. Pfaff, A. Sanchez, F. Alpizar, C. Le<strong>on</strong>,and C.M. Rodriguez. 2008. Deforestati<strong>on</strong> impacts ofenvir<strong>on</strong>mental services payments: Costa Rica’s PSAprogram 2000–2005. Centro Agr<strong>on</strong>ómico Tropical deInvestigación y Enseñanza (CATIE) mimeo.Rosenbaum, P., and D. Rubin. 1983. <strong>The</strong> central role ofthe propensity score in observati<strong>on</strong>al studies for causaleffects. Biometrika 70: 41–55.Ross, Michael. 1996. C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ality and logging reformin the tropics. In Instituti<strong>on</strong>s for envir<strong>on</strong>mental aid, ed.R.O. Keohane and M.A. Levy. Cambridge, MA: MIT.Rudel, T.K., K. Flesher, D. Bates, S. Baptista, and P.Holmgren. 2000. Tropical deforestati<strong>on</strong> literature:Geographical and historical patterns. Unasylva 203(51):11–18.Sader, S., et al. 2001. Forest change m<strong>on</strong>itoring of a remotebiosphere reserve. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Journal of RemoteSensing 22: 1937–1950.Sasser, E.N., A. Prakash, B. Cashore, and G. Auld.2006. Direct targeting as an NGO political strategy:Examining private authority regimes in the forestrysector. Business and Politics 8(3): article 1.Saunders, J., J. Eberling, and R. Nussbaum. FLEGT and<strong>REDD</strong>: Less<strong>on</strong>s and synergies. Proforest. http://www.illegal-logging.info/presentati<strong>on</strong>s/100907/Nussbaum.pdf.Schneider, R., E. Arima, A. Veríssimo, P. Barreto, and C.Souza, Jr. 2000. Amazônia sustentável: Limitantes eoportunidades para o desenvolvimento rural. SérieParcerias 1. Brasília, Brazil: World Bank and Imaz<strong>on</strong>.Schneider, R. 1995. Government and the ec<strong>on</strong>omy <strong>on</strong> theAmaz<strong>on</strong> fr<strong>on</strong>tier. World Bank Envir<strong>on</strong>ment Paper 11.Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: World Bank.Schwartzman, S., and B. Zimmerman. 2005. C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>alliances with indigenous peoples of the Amaz<strong>on</strong>.C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> Biology 19(3): 721–727.Searchinger, T., et al. 2008. Use of U.S. croplands forbiofuels increases greenhouse gases through emissi<strong>on</strong>sfrom land-use change. Science 319: 1238–1240.Seidl, F.A., J. dos Santos Vila de Silva, and A.S. Moraes.2001. Cattle ranching and deforestati<strong>on</strong> in the BrazilianPantanal. Ecological Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 36: 413–425.Seymour, F., and Dubash, N. 2000. <strong>The</strong> right c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s:<strong>The</strong> World Bank, structural adjustment, and forestrypolicy reform. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: World ResourcesInstitute.Shacklet<strong>on</strong>, S., B. Campbell, E. Wollenberg, and D.Edmunds. 2002. Devoluti<strong>on</strong> and community-basednatural resource management: Creating space forlocal people to participate and benefit? ODI NaturalResource Perspectives No. 76. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: OverseasDevelopment Institute (ODI).Sheikh, P.A. 2006. Debt-for-nature initiatives andthe Tropical Forest C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> Act: Status andimplementati<strong>on</strong>. CRS Report for C<strong>on</strong>gress; 11 October.Shively, G.E., and S. Pagiola. 2004. Agriculturalintensificati<strong>on</strong>, local labor markets, and deforestati<strong>on</strong>in the Philippines. Envir<strong>on</strong>mental and DevelopmentEc<strong>on</strong>omics 9: 241–266.Shively, G.E. 2001. Agricultural Change, rural labormarkets, and forest clearing: An illustrative case fromthe Philippines. Land Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 77(2): 268–284.Siebert, U., and G. Elwert. 2004. Combating corrupti<strong>on</strong>and illegal logging in Benin, West Africa. Journal ofSustainable Forestry 19: 239–261.Sierra, R, and E. Russman. 2006. On the efficiency of theenvir<strong>on</strong>mental service payments: A forest c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>assessment in the Osa Peninsula. Costa Rica EcologicalEc<strong>on</strong>omics 59: 131–141Sills, E., and J. Caviglia-Harris. 2008. Evoluti<strong>on</strong> of theAmaz<strong>on</strong>ian fr<strong>on</strong>tier: Land values in R<strong>on</strong>dônia, Brazil.Land Use <str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> 26: 55–67.Sills, E., et al. (forthcoming). Impact of the PSA program<strong>on</strong> land use. In Ecomarkets: Costa Rica’s experience withpayments for envir<strong>on</strong>mental services, ed. S. Pagiola.Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: World Bank.Sills, E., S. Pattanayak, P. Ferraro, and K. Alger. 2006.Abordagens analíticas na avaliação de impactos reaisde programas de c<strong>on</strong>servação. Megadiversidade 2(1–2):39–49.Sills, Erin, S. Lele, T. Holmes, and S. Pattanayak. 2003.Role of n<strong>on</strong>timber forest products in the ruralhousehold ec<strong>on</strong>omy. In Forests in a market ec<strong>on</strong>omy,ed. E. Sills and K. Abt. Dordrecht, Netherlands: KluwerAcademic Publishers.Sims, K.R.E. 2009. C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> and development:Evidence from Thai protected areas. WorkingPaper, Amherst College, Department of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics,December 2009.Sizer, Nigel. 1994. Opportunities to save and sustainablyNicholas Institute52


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New Initiativesuse the world’s forests through internati<strong>on</strong>alcooperati<strong>on</strong>. World Resources Institute: Washingt<strong>on</strong>,D.C.Smith, J., and K. Obidzinski, Subarudi, and I.Suramenggala. 2003. Illegal Logging, collusivecorrupti<strong>on</strong> and fragmented governments inKalimantan, Ind<strong>on</strong>esia. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Forestry Review5(3): 293–302.Smith, W. 2002. <strong>The</strong> global problem of illegal logging.ITTO Tropical Forest Update 12: 3–5.Somanthan, E., R. Prabhakar, B.S. Mehta. 2009.Decentralizati<strong>on</strong> for cost-effective c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>. PNAS106 (11): 4143–4147.Stocks, A., B. McMahan, and P. Taber. 2007. Indigenous,col<strong>on</strong>ist, and government impacts <strong>on</strong> Nicaragua’sBosawas Reserve. C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> Biology 21(6): 1495–1505.Sunderlin, W.D., and J. Pokam. 2002. Ec<strong>on</strong>omic crisisand forest cover change in Camero<strong>on</strong>: <strong>The</strong> roles ofmigrati<strong>on</strong>, crop diversificati<strong>on</strong>, and gender divisi<strong>on</strong>of labor. Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Development and Cultural Change50(2002): 581–606.Sunderlin, W.D., J. Hatcher, and M. Liddle. 2008. Fromexclusi<strong>on</strong> to ownership? Challenges and opportunitiesin advancing forest tenure reform. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.:Rights and Resources Initiative.Sánchez-Azofeifa, G., A. Pfaff, J. Robalino, and J.Boomhower. 2007. Costa Rica’s Payment forEnvir<strong>on</strong>mental Services Program: Intenti<strong>on</strong>,implementati<strong>on</strong> and impact. C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> Biology21(5): 1165–1173.Sánchez-Azofeifa, G.A., et al. 1999. Protected areasand c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> of biodiversity in the tropics.C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> Biology 13: 407–411.TNC (<strong>The</strong> Nature C<strong>on</strong>servancy). 2009. U.S.-Peru debt-fornatureswap. http://www.nature.org/success/perudebt.html.Torsvik, G. 2005. Foreign ec<strong>on</strong>omic aid: Should d<strong>on</strong>orscooperate? Journal of Development Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 77:503–15Uhl, C., et al. 1997. Natural resource management in theBrazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>: An integrated research approach.BioScience 47(3): 160–168.Ullsten, Ola, Salleh Mohd, and M<strong>on</strong>tague Yudelman. 1990.<strong>The</strong> Tropical Forestry Acti<strong>on</strong> Program. Report of theIndependent Review. Kuala Lumpur: FAO.USDA (United States Department of Agriculture) LaceyAct Declarati<strong>on</strong> Primer March 2009.van Kooten, G.C., R.A. Sedjo, and E.H. Bulte. 1999.Tropical deforestati<strong>on</strong>: Issues and policies. In <strong>The</strong>Internati<strong>on</strong>al Year Book of Envir<strong>on</strong>mental and ResourceEc<strong>on</strong>omics 1999/2000, ed. H. Folmer and T. Tietenberg:199–248.Vermeulen, S. 2001. Woodfuel in Africa: Crisis oradaptati<strong>on</strong>? Literature review. In Fuelwood—Crisisor balance: Workshop proceedings, G. Kohlin, ed.,Marstrand, June 6–9, 2001 (18–53). Gothenburg,Sweden: Göteborg University for CIFOR.Veríssimo, A., M.A. Cochrane, C. Souza, Jr., and R.Salomão. 2002. Priority areas for establishing nati<strong>on</strong>alforest in the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> Ecology6(1): 4.Veríssimo, A., P. Barreto, M. Mattos, R. Tarifa, and C. Uhl.1992. Logging impacts and prospects for sustainableforest management in an old Amaz<strong>on</strong> fr<strong>on</strong>tier: <strong>The</strong>case of Paragominas. Forest Ecology and Management55: 169–199.Vina, A., et al. 2007. Temporal changes in giant pandahabitat c<strong>on</strong>nectivity across boundaries of Wol<strong>on</strong>gNature Reserve, China. Ecological Applicati<strong>on</strong>s 17:1019–1030.Vincent, J. 1990. Rent capture and the feasibility of tropicalforest management. Land Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 66: 212–23.v<strong>on</strong> Amsberg, J. 1998. Ec<strong>on</strong>omic parameters ofdeforestati<strong>on</strong>. World Bank Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 12:133–153.v<strong>on</strong> Braun, J. 2008. Agriculture for sustainable ec<strong>on</strong>omicdevelopment: A global R&D initiative to avoid adeep and complex crisis. http://www.ifpri.org/pubs/speeches/20080228jvbriley.asp.v<strong>on</strong> Thünen, J.H. 1966. Der isolierte Staat in Beziehungder Landwirtschaft und Nati<strong>on</strong>alök<strong>on</strong>omie. In v<strong>on</strong>Thünen’s <strong>The</strong> Isolated State, ed. P. Hall. Oxford, UK:Pergam<strong>on</strong> Press.Vosti, S., J. Witcover, and C.L. Carpentier. 2001.Agricultural intensificati<strong>on</strong> by small-holders in theWestern Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong> – From deforestati<strong>on</strong> tosustainable land use. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: Internati<strong>on</strong>alFood <str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> Research Institute (IFPRI).Walker, R., and T.E. Smith. 1993. Tropical deforestati<strong>on</strong>and forest management under the system of c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>logging: A decisi<strong>on</strong>-theoretic analysis. Journal ofRegi<strong>on</strong>al Science 33: 387–419.Walker, R., E. Moran, and L. Anselin. 2000. Deforestati<strong>on</strong>and cattle ranching in the Brazilian Amaz<strong>on</strong>: Externalcapital and household processes. World Development28: 683–699.Whitmore, T.C. 1991. Tropical rain forest dynamicsand its implicati<strong>on</strong>s for management. In Rain ForestRegenerati<strong>on</strong> and Management, ed. A. Gómez-Pompa,T.C. Whitmore, and M. Hadley. UNESCO.Wibowo, D.H., and R.N. Byr<strong>on</strong>. 1999. Deforestati<strong>on</strong>mechanisms: A survey. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Journal of SocialEc<strong>on</strong>omics 26(1–2–3): 455–474.Winterbottom, Robert. 1990. Taking stock of the tropicalforestry acti<strong>on</strong> plan. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: WorldResources Institute.Nicholas Institute53


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesWise, M., et al. 2009. Implicati<strong>on</strong>s of limiting CO 2c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong>s for land use and energy. Science 324:1183–1186.World Bank. 2002. Less<strong>on</strong>s from the rain forest:Experiences of the pilot program to c<strong>on</strong>serve theAmaz<strong>on</strong> and Atlantic Forests of Brazil. Washingt<strong>on</strong>,D.C.: World Bank Brazil Rainforest Unit.Zbinden, S., and D.R. Lee. 2005. Paying for envir<strong>on</strong>mentalservices: An analysis of participati<strong>on</strong> in Costa Rica’sPSA Program. World Development 33(2): 255–272.Zepeda, Y., A. Blackman, A. Pfaff, and J. Robalino. 2010.Evaluating the impacts of Mexican protected areas <strong>on</strong>deforestati<strong>on</strong> from 1993–2000. RFF Working Paper.Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: Resources for the Future.Zhang, D. 2001. Faustmann in an uncertain policyenvir<strong>on</strong>ment. Forest <str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 2: 203–210.Nicholas Institute54


<str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impacts</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Deforestati<strong>on</strong>Less<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Learned</strong> from Past Experiences to Inform New InitiativesNicholas Institute55


the Nicholas Institute<strong>The</strong> Nicholas Institute for Envir<strong>on</strong>mental <str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> Soluti<strong>on</strong>s at Duke Universityis a n<strong>on</strong>partisan institute founded in 2005 to help decisi<strong>on</strong> makers in government,the private sector, and the n<strong>on</strong>profit community address criticalenvir<strong>on</strong>mental challenges. <strong>The</strong> Institute resp<strong>on</strong>ds to the demand for highqualityand timely data and acts as an “h<strong>on</strong>est broker” in policy debates byc<strong>on</strong>vening and fostering open, <strong>on</strong>going dialogue between stakeholders<strong>on</strong> all sides of the issues and providing policy-relevant analysis based <strong>on</strong>academic research. <strong>The</strong> Institute’s leadership and staff leverage the broadexpertise of Duke University as well as public and private partners worldwide.Since its incepti<strong>on</strong>, the Institute has earned a distinguished reputati<strong>on</strong>for its innovative approach to developing multilateral, n<strong>on</strong>partisan, andec<strong>on</strong>omically viable soluti<strong>on</strong>s to pressing envir<strong>on</strong>mental challenges.for more informati<strong>on</strong> please c<strong>on</strong>tact:Nicholas Institute for Envir<strong>on</strong>mental <str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> Soluti<strong>on</strong>sDuke UniversityBox 90335Durham, North Carolina 27708919.613.8709919.613.8712 faxnicholasinstitute@duke.edunicholasinstitute.duke.educopyright © 2010 Nicholas Institute for Envir<strong>on</strong>mental <str<strong>on</strong>g>Policy</str<strong>on</strong>g> Soluti<strong>on</strong>sprinted <strong>on</strong> FSC-certified, 50% post-c<strong>on</strong>sumer recycled paper

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!