11.07.2015 Views

The Transmission Mechanism and the Channels of Monetary Policy

The Transmission Mechanism and the Channels of Monetary Policy

The Transmission Mechanism and the Channels of Monetary Policy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 33.2.1 <strong>The</strong> Money View<strong>The</strong> money view places emphasis on <strong>the</strong> changes in <strong>the</strong> monetary aggregate affecting <strong>the</strong>output via interest rate channel. This view has been a st<strong>and</strong>ard feature in <strong>the</strong> traditionalKeynesian model. <strong>The</strong> mechanism can be traced by using <strong>the</strong> following schematic diagram(Mishkin, 1995):Mfl r› Ifl Yfl ,This diagram states that a contractionary monetary policy (M) leads to a rise in real interestrate (r), which raises <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> capital, <strong>the</strong>reby causing a decline in investment goods (I).Fur<strong>the</strong>r, this leads to a decline in aggregate dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> hence, a fall in output (Y).Generally, this argument can be presented in a simple IS-LM framework. <strong>The</strong> frameworkfocuses on <strong>the</strong> equilibrium position between <strong>the</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> for <strong>and</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> money todetermine <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> interest. This in turn provides <strong>the</strong> link to real spending <strong>and</strong> investment.Let <strong>the</strong> monetary equilibrium <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> LM curve be depicted by equations (3.1) - (3.3),respectively 3 ;money dem<strong>and</strong> M d = f (y,r); f 1 ’>0, f 2 ’


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 5From (3.9) a change in <strong>the</strong> money supply clearly affects <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> income through <strong>the</strong>parameters a 1 , a 2 , b 1 , f 1 , <strong>and</strong> f 2 which are all slopes <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> IS-LM curves. Thus, we canhave <strong>the</strong> money multiplier in <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> coefficient on ∆M:(3.10)1∆ y =∆ M⎛ a1 f⎜ 2 ⎞⎟ + f⎝ b − 11 a2⎠Based on equation (3.10) it is clear that <strong>the</strong> interest rate channel or <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> capitalchannel operates through <strong>the</strong> following schematic diagram:f 2 : ( ∆M ⇒ ∆r), b 1 :(∆r ⇒ ∆I) <strong>and</strong> a 1 :(∆I ⇒ ∆y) with f 1 :(∆y ⇒ ∆M d ) acting as afeedback effect.Considering <strong>the</strong> money view, obviously <strong>the</strong>re are two implicit assumptions in <strong>the</strong> model. <strong>The</strong>first is that all non-money assets are lumped toge<strong>the</strong>r into bonds. <strong>The</strong>refore, by usingWalrasian Law <strong>the</strong> bond market is in equilibrium, implying that <strong>the</strong> credit market is largelyignored in <strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard IS-LM model <strong>and</strong> is restricted to a single portfolio equation(Brunner <strong>and</strong> Meltzer, 1988). <strong>The</strong>re are two implications that can be drawn from thisassumption. First, it makes no difference whe<strong>the</strong>r banks hold loans or governmentsecurities as <strong>the</strong>ir assets. Second, it makes no difference whe<strong>the</strong>r borrowers obtain creditfrom auction markets (<strong>the</strong> commercial paper market <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> corporate bond market) orfrom <strong>the</strong> banks (Yang, 1994).


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 6<strong>The</strong> second assumption <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> money view is that all markets are perfect. All <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>borrowers are homogenous from <strong>the</strong> view point <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> lenders. Thus, <strong>the</strong> banks cannotdiscriminate between <strong>the</strong> characteristics <strong>of</strong> different borrowers. Hence, price is <strong>the</strong> onlyfactor to clear <strong>the</strong> markets or to equilibrate <strong>the</strong> markets. Consequently, <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong>endogenous credit rationing is also ruled out by <strong>the</strong> second assumption (Bernanke <strong>and</strong>Blinder, 1988).3.2.2 <strong>The</strong> Credit View<strong>The</strong> proponents <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> credit view claim that <strong>the</strong> credit market has been simply ignored by<strong>the</strong> money view. <strong>The</strong>refore, in addition to <strong>the</strong> money supply, bank credit is also important inaffecting <strong>the</strong> aggregate spending level. Bernanke <strong>and</strong> Gertler (1995) describe two possiblelinkages <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> credit channel <strong>the</strong>ory. <strong>The</strong> first one is <strong>the</strong> balance-sheet channel which placesemphasis on <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> changes in monetary policy on <strong>the</strong> borrower's balance-sheet.<strong>The</strong> second linkage is <strong>the</strong> bank lending channel which focuses on <strong>the</strong> possible effect <strong>of</strong>monetary policy actions on <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> loans by <strong>the</strong> banking system (Walsh <strong>and</strong> Wilcox,1995; Bernanke, 1993a <strong>and</strong> 1993b).Schematically, <strong>the</strong> monetary policy effects can be summarised as follows:M fl bank deposit fl bank loans fl I fl Y fl ,Thus, contractionary monetary policy leads to a fall in bank reserves <strong>and</strong> bank deposits,subsequently this results in a decline in bank loans, in turn leading to a decline in investmentspending <strong>and</strong> a fall in output.


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 7To facilitate <strong>the</strong> schematic diagram above, let us consider a variant <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> IS-LM model,based on <strong>the</strong> framework set out by Bernanke <strong>and</strong> Blinder (1988). <strong>The</strong>ir model allows rolesfor both “credit” (bank loans) <strong>and</strong> money ra<strong>the</strong>r than money-only as in <strong>the</strong> traditional IS-LM framework. An explicit assumption made regarding this model is that loans <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rauction-market credit (“bonds”) are viewed as imperfect substitutes, hence, allowing <strong>the</strong>model to include <strong>the</strong> credit <strong>and</strong> bonds market in addition to <strong>the</strong> money market 4 . By doingso, <strong>the</strong> borrowers <strong>and</strong> lenders may choose between bonds <strong>and</strong> loans according to <strong>the</strong>interest rates on <strong>the</strong> two credit instruments. By setting up this particular assumption, <strong>the</strong> LMcurve is <strong>the</strong>n derived from a set <strong>of</strong> portfolio-balance conditions on <strong>the</strong> two-asset world:money <strong>and</strong> credit (“bonds”). To derive <strong>the</strong> credit curve or “commodities <strong>and</strong> credit” (CC)curve, first, let <strong>the</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> for loans be:- + +dL = L i y( ρ , , )(3.11)where ρ is <strong>the</strong> interest rate on loans, i is <strong>the</strong> interest rate on bonds, y is <strong>the</strong> income tocapture <strong>the</strong> transactional dem<strong>and</strong> for credit, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> signs indicate <strong>the</strong> relationship <strong>of</strong> eachvariable with respect to <strong>the</strong> loans dem<strong>and</strong>. Second, <strong>the</strong> loan supply function is derived froma simplified bank balance sheet as follows:assetsreserves (R)bonds (B b )loans (L s )liabilitiesdeposits (D)4 Karl Brunner <strong>and</strong> Allan Meltzer (1972, 1988) also develop similar models. An application on <strong>the</strong> UKdata using a variant <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Brunner <strong>and</strong> Meltzer model can be found in Kent Mat<strong>the</strong>ws <strong>and</strong> ChrisIoannidis (1992).


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 8where R= σD + E; σ is <strong>the</strong> required reserves ratio, <strong>and</strong> E is <strong>the</strong> excess reserves. Thus<strong>the</strong> bank’s adding-up constraint is: B b + L s + E = D (1-σ ). <strong>The</strong>refore <strong>the</strong> loans supplyfunction is as follows:+ī σ (3.12)sL = l(r, ) D(1 - )with a similar equation for B b <strong>and</strong> E. <strong>The</strong> clearing condition for <strong>the</strong> loan market is:L d = L s (3.13)L( ρ ,i, y) = λ( ρ,i) D(1 - σ)(3.14)<strong>The</strong> money market is described by a conventional LM curve. Banks hold excess reservesequal to ε(i)D(1 - σ). <strong>The</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> deposits is equal to bank reserves, R, times <strong>the</strong>money multiplierm = m(i).R; (3.15)where m(i) = [1/ε(1-σ)+σ] 5 .<strong>The</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> for deposits isD d += D( i, y)(3.16)By using equations (3.15) <strong>and</strong> (3.16), (D = m(i)R) to replace D on <strong>the</strong> right side <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>equation (3.14), we haveL = λ[ ρ, i] m( i) R( 1 - ρ)(3.17)


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 9Taking <strong>the</strong> total differentiation on (3.17)withdL = λ R( 1- σ) midi + m( i) R( 1- σ)( λρdρ + λ idi) + λm( 1-σ)dR (3.18)m i > 0 ; λ ρ > 0; λ i > 0.Next, using total differentiation to solve <strong>the</strong> left h<strong>and</strong> side <strong>of</strong> equation (3.14), we havedL = Lρdρ + Lidi + Lydy(3.19)withL ρ < 0;L i > 0;L y > 0.Equating equations (3.18) <strong>and</strong> (3.19), <strong>the</strong>n rearranging to solve for ρ as a function <strong>of</strong> i, y,<strong>and</strong> R; we have 6Lρ- m( i) R( 1- σ) λ ρ) dρ = λR( 1- σ) mi + m( i) R( 1- σ) λi - Li) di + (-Ly)dy+ mλm( 1 - σ)dR(3.20)Thus, <strong>the</strong> loan rate that clears <strong>the</strong> loan market can be stated as follows:ρ =+ + -Φ( i, y, R )(3.21)5 −Is solved as follows: m ≡ D / ( E + RR ) ; ∴m ≡ D / [ ε( D)( 1 − σ) + σD];∴ m( i) = [ ε( i)( 1− σ) + σ) ] 16 To get equation (4) <strong>of</strong> Bernanke <strong>and</strong> Blinder (1988;p.436).


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 10Equation (3.21) shows that <strong>the</strong> interest rate on loans is positively related to interest rateon bonds <strong>and</strong> income, but inversely related to bank reserves. To solve for <strong>the</strong> aggregatedem<strong>and</strong> curve, Bernanke <strong>and</strong> Blinder (1988) use <strong>the</strong> following generic IS curve:y= Y( i, ρ )(3.22)<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>n by substituting equation (3.21) into (3.22), we gety = Y( i, Φ { i, y, R}),(3.23)<strong>the</strong> so-called “commodities <strong>and</strong> credit” (CC) curve in Bernanke <strong>and</strong> Blinder’s term. Figure3.1 shows both <strong>the</strong> CC <strong>and</strong> LM curves in a (i,y) space.iLMCCFigure 3.1 <strong>The</strong> Commodities-Credit (CC) <strong>and</strong> LM CurvesY


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 11As discussed by Bernanke <strong>and</strong> Blinder (1988; p. 436), <strong>the</strong> CC curve 7 is negativelysloped like an IS curve but it is shifted by monetary policy 8 , R, <strong>and</strong> by credit shock thataffects ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> loans dem<strong>and</strong> function, L(.) or <strong>the</strong> loans supply function, λ(.).<strong>The</strong>re is one disadvantage if one wants to apply this framework in a developing country'scontext. <strong>The</strong> model assumes that <strong>the</strong> loan market is always in equilibrium. This scenariomay not be true in <strong>the</strong> context <strong>of</strong> developing countries simply due to heavy governmentintervention in <strong>the</strong> loan market during <strong>the</strong> pre-liberalisation period i.e. interest-rate ceilings<strong>and</strong> quantitative credit controls. Thus, it could be possible for <strong>the</strong> transmission mechanismprocess to exist through <strong>the</strong> credit rationing channel. Fur<strong>the</strong>r discussion on <strong>the</strong> creditrationing channel is presented in Section 3.4.7 <strong>The</strong> CC curve reduces to <strong>the</strong> IS curve if loans <strong>and</strong> bonds are assumed to be perfect substitutes ei<strong>the</strong>rto borrowers (Lρ →-∞) or to lenders (λρ→∞) or if commodity dem<strong>and</strong> is insensitive to <strong>the</strong> loan rate(Yρ=0). (Ibid; p. 436)8 Graphically, <strong>the</strong> ambiguity arises because an increase in R shifts both <strong>the</strong> CC <strong>and</strong> LM curves outward.Economically, <strong>the</strong> credit channel makes monetary policy more expansionary than <strong>the</strong> IS/LM <strong>and</strong><strong>the</strong>refore raises <strong>the</strong> transaction dem<strong>and</strong> for money by more than in <strong>the</strong> conventional model. (Ibid; p.437).


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 123.3 <strong>The</strong> Development <strong>of</strong>, <strong>and</strong> Empirical Evidence Relating To <strong>the</strong> Credit <strong>and</strong><strong>the</strong> Money <strong>Channels</strong>A summary <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> empirical findings <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> previous studies conducted in this area ispresented in Tables 3.1 <strong>and</strong> 3.2. Tables 3.1 summarises <strong>the</strong> empirical evidence from <strong>the</strong>developed countries, while Table 3.2 highlights <strong>the</strong> empirical evidence from <strong>the</strong> developingcountries. Empirical evidence from <strong>the</strong> developed countries available so far has providedsome support to <strong>the</strong> credit as well as <strong>the</strong> money channels hypo<strong>the</strong>sis. However, <strong>the</strong>evidence for <strong>the</strong> developing countries is somewhat blurred.3.3.1 Evidence from <strong>the</strong> Industrialised CountriesTable 3.1 summarises <strong>the</strong> empirical evidence using <strong>the</strong> data set on most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> industrialisedcountries. Interestingly, most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se studies support <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> money as wellas <strong>the</strong> credit/bank lending channel in <strong>the</strong> transmission mechanism process (Bernanke (1986);Bernanke <strong>and</strong> Blinder (1988); Bernanke <strong>and</strong> Blinder (1992); Kashyap, Stein, <strong>and</strong> Wilcox(1993); Walsh <strong>and</strong> Wilcox (1995); <strong>and</strong> Oliner <strong>and</strong> Rudebush (1995)); amongst o<strong>the</strong>rs.<strong>The</strong>se studies have focused on <strong>the</strong> relationship between aggregate income, commercial bankloans, money stock, interest rates, <strong>and</strong> money indicators in <strong>the</strong> USA. For exampleBernanke (1986) used <strong>the</strong> contemporaneous structural vector autoregression approach(SVAR) <strong>and</strong> imposed covariance restrictions to gain identification. <strong>The</strong> credit variable usedby Bernanke is <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> commercial bank loans extended by <strong>the</strong> intermediaries.


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 13Ano<strong>the</strong>r study by Bernanke <strong>and</strong> Blinder (1988) which employed an extended version <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> IS-LM model <strong>and</strong> incorporated <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> borrowing by households <strong>and</strong> businesssectors as a credit variable, found that <strong>the</strong> money shocks became much more importantrelative to credit-dem<strong>and</strong> shocks in <strong>the</strong> 1980’s. However <strong>the</strong>re is no strong evidence toreject <strong>the</strong> role <strong>of</strong> credit dem<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> thus warrant a symmetric treatment on money <strong>and</strong>credit. In <strong>the</strong>ir model, Bernanke <strong>and</strong> Blinder (1988) have assumed imperfect substitutabilitybetween money, bonds <strong>and</strong> loans, thus allowing both <strong>the</strong> borrowers <strong>and</strong> lenders to choosebetween bonds <strong>and</strong> loans according to <strong>the</strong> interest rates on <strong>the</strong> two credit instruments, i.e.interest rates on loans <strong>and</strong> interest rates on bonds.Unfortunately, focusing alone on commercial bank loans still does not resolve <strong>the</strong> issue. Forexample, a recent study by Romer <strong>and</strong> Romer (1990) rejects <strong>the</strong> role <strong>of</strong> bank loans as apart <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> transmission mechanism process in <strong>the</strong> USA. Romer <strong>and</strong> Romer (1990) employsix ‘episodes’ 9 <strong>of</strong> restrictive monetary policy which <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve appears to havedeliberately used in an attempt to reduce <strong>the</strong> inflation rate during an economic slowdown.<strong>The</strong>y argue that <strong>the</strong> purpose <strong>of</strong> using <strong>the</strong>se ‘episodes’ as indicators <strong>of</strong> monetary policy is toovercome a difficulty in finding <strong>the</strong> legitimate monetary policy proxy to truly represent <strong>the</strong>Fed’s actions 10 . <strong>The</strong> estimates <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> forecast errors on both <strong>the</strong> money supply <strong>and</strong> bankloans show that <strong>the</strong> effect <strong>of</strong> loans’ forecast errors is smaller than <strong>the</strong> forecast errors <strong>of</strong>money supply, <strong>the</strong>refore indicating that <strong>the</strong> money channel transmits more information to <strong>the</strong>real sector than <strong>the</strong> credit channel does.9 <strong>The</strong> series <strong>of</strong> episodes were summarised in Table 3.1.10 Most studies in <strong>the</strong> USA use <strong>the</strong> federal funds rate as a monetary policy indicator. See, for example,Bernanke <strong>and</strong> Blider (1992) <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r studies summarised in Table 3.1.


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 14However, Yang (1994) criticised <strong>the</strong> Romer <strong>and</strong> Romer’s (1990) finding. Yang (1994)argues that, first, Romer <strong>and</strong> Romer (1990) have only tested <strong>the</strong> monetary policy during <strong>the</strong>period <strong>of</strong> tightening <strong>and</strong> not in <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> easing. Thus, <strong>the</strong> comprehensiveness <strong>of</strong> usingRomer ‘episode’ as a proxy for monetary policy is questionable. <strong>The</strong> second critique is thata strong tightening <strong>of</strong> monetary policy may cause a greater decline in <strong>the</strong> money supply thanin <strong>the</strong> credit supply. If this is <strong>the</strong> case in reality, <strong>the</strong>n Romer <strong>and</strong> Romer (1990) may havedrawn an incorrect conclusion.However, <strong>the</strong> study by Gertler <strong>and</strong> Gilchrist (1995) reconfirm <strong>the</strong> evidence found by Romer<strong>and</strong> Romer (1990). Gertler <strong>and</strong> Gilchrist argue that <strong>the</strong> bank credit is more likely to bedriven by dem<strong>and</strong> factors than by monetary policy because <strong>the</strong> decline in bank credit growthlags behind <strong>the</strong> decline in money growth. Similar criticism was made by Cecchetti (1995)on <strong>the</strong> Wash <strong>and</strong> Wilcox (1995) paper.Fur<strong>the</strong>r investigation by Bernanke <strong>and</strong> Blinder (1992) obtained similar evidence to <strong>the</strong>irearlier study in 1988. By using innovation in 3-month Treasury Bill rate to captureexogenous shifts in monetary policy, <strong>the</strong>y found that <strong>the</strong> decline in bank loans following amonetary policy tightening represents <strong>the</strong> credit channel. In consequence, <strong>the</strong> loan supply isrestricted via a bank lending channel. Thus, <strong>the</strong>y interpret this latter evidence as consistentwith <strong>the</strong> credit view.<strong>The</strong> previous studies also show that <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> credit channel is not only through <strong>the</strong>bank’s balance sheet but also through <strong>the</strong> broad credit aggregate, i.e. total domestic


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 15nonfinancial debt, total debt <strong>and</strong> total credit. See, for example, Bernanke (1983),Fackler (1990), <strong>and</strong> Fackler <strong>and</strong> Rogers (1993), amongst o<strong>the</strong>rs. In order to probe <strong>the</strong>usefulness <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> broad credit aggregate, Bernanke (1983) utilised <strong>the</strong> total net credit (whichis <strong>the</strong> aggregate outst<strong>and</strong>ing indebtness <strong>of</strong> all US non financial borrowers) in addition tooutput (GNP), using <strong>the</strong> US historical data from 1959 to 1980. <strong>The</strong> results show that totalnet credit is a better predictor <strong>of</strong> output than monetary aggregates (M1, M2, M3, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>monetary base). This finding has been reinforced by Friedman (1988).Fackler (1990) also studied <strong>the</strong> role <strong>of</strong> public debt <strong>and</strong> private debt in <strong>the</strong> US usingBernanke’s (1986) contemporaneous structural VAR model. Fackler (1990) found out thatshocks in public debt have no significant effect on <strong>the</strong> interest rate, prices, or output but incontrast, shock in private credit growth significantly lowers <strong>the</strong> interest rate <strong>and</strong> inflation in<strong>the</strong> first years. A private credit shock also significantly lowers output with a lag <strong>of</strong> aboutthree <strong>and</strong> a half years. Based on Fackler’s (1990) study, Fackler <strong>and</strong> Rogers (1993)extended <strong>the</strong> analysis in an open-economy model to include <strong>the</strong> exchange rates as ano<strong>the</strong>rpotential channel <strong>of</strong> transmission mechanism. Using <strong>the</strong> US quarterly data from 1973:II to1989:I, <strong>the</strong> results <strong>of</strong> estimation again reconfirmed <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> credit channel <strong>and</strong>significant effects from changes in exchange rate on credit aggregate.In recent literature development, however, new debate has emerged to identify <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong>credit market imperfections by analyzing <strong>the</strong> response <strong>of</strong> different forms <strong>of</strong> credit <strong>and</strong>different types <strong>of</strong> borrowers to monetary policy changes. <strong>The</strong>se studies have beenconducted by Kashyap, Stein <strong>and</strong> Wilcox (1993), Oliner <strong>and</strong> Rudebusch (1995), Gertler


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 16<strong>and</strong> Gilchrist (1995), Oliner <strong>and</strong> Rudebusch (1996), <strong>and</strong> Bernanke, Gertler, <strong>and</strong>Gilchrist (1996), amongst o<strong>the</strong>rs.<strong>The</strong>se authors rely on <strong>the</strong> fact that for a large class <strong>of</strong> borrowers, particularly households<strong>and</strong> small firms, close substitutes for bank credit are unavailable. <strong>The</strong>y must, <strong>the</strong>refore,depend on banks for external finance. <strong>The</strong>refore, any shock on <strong>the</strong> asset side <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> bankbalance sheet has important real effects (Gertler <strong>and</strong> Gilchrist, 1995). An important policyimplication is that monetary policy works at least in part by altering <strong>the</strong> flow <strong>of</strong> bank creditor by influencing <strong>the</strong> asset side <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> bank balance sheet.<strong>The</strong> proponents <strong>of</strong> broad credit aggregate fur<strong>the</strong>r argue that in order for <strong>the</strong> credit channel tooperate, <strong>the</strong> credit measures must be imperfect substitutes for o<strong>the</strong>r sources <strong>of</strong> finance(Oliner <strong>and</strong> Rudebusch,1995). Thus, any narrow focus on types <strong>of</strong> debt finance may omitvaluable information such as a shift in financing patterns after a change in monetary policy.This is <strong>the</strong> main criticism <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> study by Kashyap et. al. (1993), since <strong>the</strong>y used commercialpaper as <strong>the</strong> only form <strong>of</strong> nonbank debt. In fact, o<strong>the</strong>r sources <strong>of</strong> nonbank finance such as<strong>the</strong> issuance <strong>of</strong> longer-term debt, trade credit <strong>and</strong> loans from finance companies can also beclassified as nonbank debt. Hence, Oliner <strong>and</strong> Rudebusch (1995) proposed <strong>the</strong> used <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>mix <strong>of</strong> bank <strong>and</strong> nonbank debt to describe <strong>the</strong> range <strong>of</strong> nonbank financing options availableto small <strong>and</strong> large firms or what <strong>the</strong>y have called <strong>the</strong> broad credit channel. <strong>The</strong>ir study alsoincorporated <strong>the</strong> ‘Romer episodes’ <strong>and</strong> changes in <strong>the</strong> federal fund rates as price indicators<strong>of</strong> monetary policy stance. As <strong>the</strong>y expected, <strong>the</strong> results showed an insignificant relationshipbetween monetary policy stance <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> mix <strong>of</strong> short-term debt for both small <strong>and</strong> large


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 17firms. However, when total debt stocks were estimated, <strong>the</strong> result indicated strongly thatmonetary tightening induced a significant shift in overall lending.A fur<strong>the</strong>r study by Oliner <strong>and</strong> Rudebusch (1996) supported <strong>the</strong> existence <strong>of</strong> a broad creditchannel <strong>and</strong> its operation among small firms. This result showed that a tightening <strong>of</strong>monetary policy affects small firms more than large firms. <strong>The</strong>refore, <strong>the</strong> main implicationfrom <strong>the</strong>se studies is that using disaggregated forms <strong>of</strong> credit <strong>and</strong> different types <strong>of</strong>borrowers <strong>of</strong>fers new evidence on <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> a credit channel.Studies on <strong>the</strong> United Kingdom data has been empirically tested by Mat<strong>the</strong>ws <strong>and</strong> Ioannidis(1992), <strong>and</strong> Dale <strong>and</strong> Halden (1993, 1995), amongst o<strong>the</strong>rs. <strong>The</strong>se studies employed <strong>the</strong>VAR method <strong>of</strong> estimation. <strong>The</strong> former used aggregated data, while <strong>the</strong> latter useddisaggregated data relating to <strong>the</strong> personal, company <strong>and</strong> real sectors. <strong>The</strong> main findinguncovered by Mat<strong>the</strong>ws <strong>and</strong> Ioannidis (1992) showed that both credit growth <strong>and</strong> M0played an important role in <strong>the</strong> determination <strong>of</strong> inflation <strong>and</strong> output in <strong>the</strong> UK. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rh<strong>and</strong>, Dale <strong>and</strong> Halden (1993) found that <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> banks in <strong>the</strong> transmissionmechanism process <strong>and</strong> it effects varied across sectors. <strong>The</strong>y also argued that sectoralmeasures <strong>of</strong> money <strong>and</strong> credit provided more accurate <strong>and</strong> timely signals <strong>of</strong> futuremovements in inflation <strong>and</strong> output.Recently, Gerlach <strong>and</strong> Smets (1995) employed <strong>the</strong> structural VAR to investigate <strong>the</strong>monetary policy transmission mechanism in <strong>the</strong> G-7 countries using data set spanning 1979:1to 1993:4. As <strong>the</strong>y argued, in order to enhance <strong>the</strong> comparability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> results across


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 18countries, <strong>the</strong> short-term interest rate was used as a proxy <strong>of</strong> monetary policy stance 11 .<strong>The</strong> results ashowed slight variations across countries. <strong>The</strong>ir point estimates suggested that<strong>the</strong> output effects <strong>of</strong> a monetary policy tightening were smallest in France <strong>and</strong> Italy; <strong>and</strong>largest in Canada, Germany <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> United States; however, <strong>the</strong> effects in Japan <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>United Kingdom fell somewhere between <strong>the</strong> two groups above.By <strong>and</strong> large, <strong>the</strong> above studies indicated that not only does money does matter to <strong>the</strong>monetary policy transmission mechanism, but both <strong>the</strong> narrow <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> broad credit channelsplay a similar role. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> survey also showed that it is very hard to find anyempirical evidence in <strong>the</strong> context <strong>of</strong> developing countries. This is not a surprise, in fact it isto be expected, because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> basic question as to whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>re exists a clearimplementation <strong>of</strong> monetary policy among <strong>the</strong> developing countries. Since <strong>the</strong> ongoingdebate among <strong>the</strong> developing countries is about <strong>the</strong> credit rationing phenomenon, <strong>the</strong>following subsections highlight <strong>the</strong> issue specifically.11 <strong>The</strong>y estimate a three-variable SVAR - real output, prices <strong>and</strong> short-term interest rate.


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 19Table 3.1: Selected Empirical Studies Relating to Developed Countriesauthor (year)Benjamin M.Friedman (1988)Ben S. Bernanke(1986)Ben S. Bernanke &Alan S. Blinder(1988)country/datafrequency<strong>the</strong> USA;quarterly data1953:I - 1978:IV<strong>the</strong> USA;quarterly data1953:I - 1984:IVseasonally adjusted<strong>the</strong> USA,quarterly data1974:I - 1985:IVmodel / method <strong>of</strong> estimation variables used findings1. st<strong>and</strong>ard 3-variable VAR; X,P, C2. st<strong>and</strong>ard 4-variable VAR; X,P, M, C;both models used 8-quarterlagged, all variables used innatural logarithms,structural reduced-form VAR;six variables ; Y, P, G, M1, B, C;in <strong>the</strong> estimation all variableswere in log-level or logdifferencedformInstrumental Variables (IV);<strong>of</strong> logarithmic partialadjustment modelreal GNP,X; price deflator, P;total nonfinancial debt (credit),C; M1/M2/M3, M;real GNP, Y; <strong>the</strong> GNP pricedeflator, P; real defencespending,G; <strong>the</strong> M1 moneystock, <strong>the</strong> monetary base, B; <strong>the</strong>credit variables, C, is <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong>commercial bank loans,mortgages held by S&L, <strong>and</strong>mortgages plus ‘o<strong>the</strong>r loans’held by mutual savings banks;<strong>the</strong> nominal interest rate, R is<strong>the</strong> 3-month treasury bill ratereal GNP, y; GNP deflator, P;prime rate, p; 3-month treasurybill rate, r; credit aggregate is<strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> intermediatedborrowing by households <strong>and</strong>business (derived from <strong>the</strong> flow<strong>of</strong>-fundsdata)<strong>The</strong> results show that both money <strong>and</strong> creditconvey <strong>the</strong> same information about <strong>the</strong>determination <strong>of</strong> prices, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>refore support atwo-target monetary policy framework based onboth money <strong>and</strong> credit.Two conclusions were highlighted;First, it appears that credit shocks are importantfor output; <strong>and</strong> second, however money <strong>and</strong> creditare approximately equal important forces in <strong>the</strong>monetary transmission mechanism.<strong>The</strong> results <strong>of</strong> estimation show that <strong>the</strong> moneydem<strong>and</strong>shocks became much more importantrelative to credit-dem<strong>and</strong> shocks in <strong>the</strong> 1980’s.However <strong>the</strong>re is no strong evidence to reject <strong>the</strong>role <strong>of</strong> credit-dem<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> thus warrant asymmetric treatment on money <strong>and</strong> credit.


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 20author (year)Karl Brunner &Allan H. Meltzer(1988)Christina D. Romer& David H. Romer(1990)James S. Fackler(1990)John McCallum(1991)country/datafrequencymodel / method <strong>of</strong> estimation variables used findings<strong>the</strong> USA Multi-asset model not mentioned explicitly in this This study moves beyond <strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard IS-LM‘summary’ article. However, framework by incorporating a credit market <strong>and</strong><strong>the</strong>ir model can be traced in introducing a general substitution process, loan(ed.) Stein, 1976, pp. 69-103 rationing supplements interest rate rationing,relative to price changes. <strong>The</strong> results show that<strong>the</strong>y are part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> monetary transmissionmechanism process.<strong>the</strong> USAmonthly data1941-1984<strong>the</strong> USAquarterly data1960:I - 1984:IV<strong>the</strong> USAquarterly data1947:III - 1986:IVSt. Louis EquationOLS2SLSIVstructural VAR as suggested byBernanke (1986)all data are seasonally adjustedexcept for <strong>the</strong> interest rateCredit rationing model <strong>of</strong>Blinder (1987)Bank lending is loans made bycommercial banks; Moneystock M1, anti-inflationaryperiods/dummies (Oct 1947,Sept 1955, Dec 1968, April1974, Aug 1978, <strong>and</strong> Oct 1979);3-month Treasury bill rate,Industrial production;real military spending; <strong>the</strong>monetary base; Corporate bondrate; M2; <strong>the</strong> GNP deflator; realGNP; <strong>the</strong> federal privatecomponents <strong>of</strong> total nonfinancialdomestic debtlog <strong>of</strong> real GNP; two types <strong>of</strong>monetary variables (1. residual<strong>of</strong> Barro-type quarterly moneyequation, 2. detrended growthrate <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> actual money supplyM1); dummies to indicatevarious credit rationing odcredit crunch periodsBy using six ‘periods’ <strong>of</strong> restrictive monetarypolicy, <strong>the</strong>y found that <strong>the</strong> forecast errors <strong>of</strong>credit supply is smaller than <strong>the</strong> forecast errors<strong>of</strong> money supply. This implies that <strong>the</strong> moneychannel transmits more information than <strong>the</strong>credit channel.real military spending is a proxy for <strong>the</strong>exogenous elements in fiscal policy. <strong>The</strong> resultsestablish <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> credit (in total) inexplaining <strong>the</strong> relationship between credit <strong>and</strong>output.This study concerns <strong>the</strong> microeconomic aspect <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> credit channel. <strong>The</strong> results <strong>of</strong> estimationshow that <strong>the</strong> credit rationing mechanism exists<strong>and</strong> accounts for about half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> totalcontribution <strong>of</strong> monetary shocks to fluctuationsin GNP.


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 21author (year)Ben S. Bernanke &Alan S. Blinder(1992)country/datafrequency<strong>the</strong> USAmonthly data1959:7 - 1989:12model / method <strong>of</strong> estimation variables used findingssix different five-variable VAR’swere testedall data were seasonally adjustedlog <strong>of</strong> CPI; log <strong>of</strong> M1 <strong>and</strong> M2;federal funds rate; 3-monthTBR; 10-year treasury bondrate; nonborrowed reserves <strong>of</strong>depository institutionsthree conclusions have been drawn from thisstudy. [1] <strong>the</strong> fund rate is a good indicator <strong>of</strong>monetary policy even for <strong>the</strong> period after 1979. [2]nominal interest rates are good forecasters <strong>of</strong>real variable. [3] monetary policy works in partby affecting <strong>the</strong> composition <strong>of</strong> bank assets., i.e.tight monetary policy affects <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> bankloans.Kent Mat<strong>the</strong>ws <strong>and</strong>Chris Ioannidis(1992)<strong>the</strong> UKquarterly data1970:I - 1990:Istructural VAR modelunadjusted data<strong>the</strong> annual growth rates <strong>of</strong>credit; inflation; real income;M4 <strong>and</strong> M0<strong>the</strong> results show that [1] <strong>the</strong> existence <strong>of</strong> long-runrelationship between narrow money <strong>and</strong> inflationrate, [2] both credit growth <strong>and</strong> M0 growth playsan important role in <strong>the</strong> determination <strong>of</strong> inflation<strong>and</strong> output, [3] credit shock affects <strong>the</strong> variance <strong>of</strong>inflation but not its mean,; <strong>the</strong> mean rate <strong>of</strong>inflation is dominated by <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> M0,[4] M0 is a useful “advance indicator”Spencer Dale &Andrew Halden(1993)<strong>the</strong> UKmonthly data1974:6 - 1992:10VAR model(estimate disaggregated dataaccording to sector; a. personalsector, b. company sector, c. realsector)industrial production; retailsales, bank lending <strong>and</strong> deposits<strong>of</strong> both banks <strong>and</strong> buildingsocietiesThis paper focuses on <strong>the</strong> role <strong>of</strong> banks in <strong>the</strong>transmission mechanism process. <strong>The</strong> evidencesuggests <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> banks in this processbut varies across sectors. In addition, sectoralmeasures <strong>of</strong> money <strong>and</strong> credit provide moreaccurate <strong>and</strong> timely signals <strong>of</strong> future movementsin inflation.


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 22author (year)Anil K. Kashyap,Jeremy C. Stein, &David W. Wilcox(1993)James S. Fackler &John H. Rogers(1993)Pierre Duguay(1994)country/datafrequency<strong>the</strong> USAquarterly data1963:I - 1989:IV<strong>the</strong> USAquarterly data1973:II - 1989:ICanadaquarterly data1970:I - 1990:IVmodel / method <strong>of</strong> estimation variables used findingsstructural modelVAR model[Bernanke (1986) model]single reduced-form equationcommercial paper; commercialbank loans; bank loans as afraction <strong>of</strong> total short-termexternal finance; <strong>the</strong> spreadbetween prime commercialpaper rates <strong>and</strong> TBR;Investment <strong>and</strong> inventory data;business cycle indicatorsfederal governmentexpenditure; GNP deflator;trade-weighted value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> USdollar; M2; total domesticnonfinancial debt; real GNP;federal funds ratereal GDP; 8-quarter MA <strong>of</strong>quarterly changes in real shortterm interest rates (90-daycommercial paper rate minus<strong>the</strong> fourth quarter growth ratein <strong>the</strong> GDP deflator); 12-quarterMA <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> growth in realcommodity prices; 8-quarterMA <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> change in fiscalstance; 12-quarter <strong>of</strong> MA <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>rate <strong>of</strong> growth in <strong>the</strong> realexchange rate between Canada<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> USA.this study finds that tighter monetary policy leadsto a shift in firms’ mix <strong>of</strong> external financing:commercial paper issuance rises while bankloans fall. This suggests that contractionarypolicy reduce loan supply, thus affect investment,interest rates <strong>and</strong> output.This study provides two main findings[1] changes in credit are at least as important asany o<strong>the</strong>r variable in explaining movements inoutput, prices <strong>and</strong> interest rates[2] <strong>the</strong>re is a significant effect from changes inexchange rates on credit.<strong>the</strong> result emphasizes <strong>the</strong> transmissionmechanism through interest rates <strong>and</strong> exchangerate ra<strong>the</strong>r than through changes in monetaryaggregates.


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 23author (year)Kai J. Yang (1994)John B. Taylor(1995)Ben. S. Bernanke &Mark Gertler(1995)Stephen D. Oliner &Glenn D. Rudebusch(1995)country/datafrequency<strong>the</strong> USAquarterly data1973:IV - 1992:IIUnited States,Germany & Japanearly 1970s to mid-1990s<strong>the</strong> USAmonthly data1965:1 - 1993:12quarterly data <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>US ManufacturingSector,1973:IV - 1991:IImodel / method <strong>of</strong> estimation variables used findingsVAR modelfinancial market pricesframeworkVAR systemstructural model (Kashyap,Stein & Wilcox’s Model; 1993)Used three credit rationingproxies [1]. <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> bankloans to <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> bank loans<strong>and</strong> commercial paperoutst<strong>and</strong>ing, [2] <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong>banks, commercial <strong>and</strong>industrial loans to small firmsto similar loans to large firms,[3] <strong>the</strong> percentage <strong>of</strong> surveyrespondents indicating thatcredit has become more difficultto obtainshort-term interest rates, bondyields, exchange rateslog <strong>of</strong> real GDP; log <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> GDPdeflator; log <strong>of</strong> an index <strong>of</strong>commodity prices <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>federal funds rate; creditaggregates;debt (bank loans, commercialpaper, o<strong>the</strong>r nonbank debt);monetary policy indicators (1.Dummy <strong>of</strong> ‘Romer Dates’, 2.changes in <strong>the</strong> federal fundsrate<strong>The</strong> <strong>the</strong>sis argues that credit rationing is animportant third channel <strong>of</strong> transmissionmechanism. <strong>The</strong> results <strong>of</strong> VAR analysis support<strong>the</strong> hypo<strong>the</strong>sis.this paper focuses on transmission mechanismthrough <strong>the</strong> financial market prices ra<strong>the</strong>r thanfinancial market quantities. This study <strong>of</strong>ferssimilar evidence as previously discussed.<strong>The</strong> result supports <strong>the</strong> existence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> creditchannel.<strong>The</strong>ir evidence is consistent with a broad view <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> credit channel that emphasizes <strong>the</strong>information asymmetries faced by all lenders.


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 24author (year)Mark Gertler <strong>and</strong>Simon Gilchrist(1995)country/datafrequency<strong>the</strong> USAquarterly data1975:I - 1991:IVmodel / method <strong>of</strong> estimation variables used findingsVAR model<strong>the</strong> log <strong>of</strong> (etrended) real GNP;<strong>the</strong> inflation rate; <strong>the</strong> nominalFederal Funds Rate; <strong>the</strong> log <strong>of</strong>financial variables (i.e. totalloans, business loans, totalsecurities, real estate loans,large time deposits, consumerloans - all <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se variables indisaggregated form accordingto small <strong>and</strong> large firms)<strong>The</strong> authors argue that <strong>the</strong>re is a strikingdifference in response <strong>of</strong> credit flows to smallversus large borrowers, potentially consistentwith <strong>the</strong> view that credit market imperfectionshelp propagate <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> monetary policy.Stephen D. Oliner &Glenn D. Rudebusch(1996)quarterly data <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>US ManufacturingSector,1958:IV - 1992:IVInvestment equation for small<strong>and</strong> large firms data wereseasonally adjustednet sales; cash flow; capitalstock investment spending; cost<strong>of</strong> capital;Using data from <strong>the</strong> US manufacturing sector, <strong>the</strong>authors tested for <strong>the</strong> existence <strong>of</strong> a broad creditchannel for monetary policy; which operatesthrough <strong>the</strong> total supply <strong>of</strong> loans. This studyfur<strong>the</strong>r focused on <strong>the</strong> relationship betweeninternal funds <strong>and</strong> business investment.<strong>Monetary</strong> tightening affects small firms morethan large firms. In contrast, after a monetaryeasing, <strong>the</strong> relationship is little changed for allfirms. This evidence supports <strong>the</strong> existence <strong>of</strong> abroad credit channel.


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 25author (year)Carl E. Walsh <strong>and</strong>James A. Wilcox(1995)country/datafrequency<strong>the</strong> USAmonthly data1955:01 - 1994:12model / method <strong>of</strong> estimation variables used findingsVAR model<strong>the</strong> log <strong>of</strong> Coincident Indicators(i.e. real personal income lesstransfer, industrial production,real manufacturing trade sales,employees on non agriculturalpayrolls); inflation; nominalfederal funds rates; primerates; <strong>and</strong> real bank loan.<strong>The</strong> results consistent with <strong>the</strong> credit view -supply <strong>of</strong> bank loans had less effect on banklending than output. Loan shock was a factor in<strong>the</strong> boom in <strong>the</strong> late 1980s <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> recession in<strong>the</strong> early 1990s.


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 273.3.2 <strong>The</strong> Microeconomic Aspect <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Credit Channel - <strong>the</strong> Credit RationingPhenomenon<strong>The</strong> lending channel or <strong>the</strong> bank loan channel is closely related to earlier work on <strong>the</strong>microeconomic aspect <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> credit channel - <strong>the</strong> credit rationing channel. As argued byMeltzer (1995), although credit rationing is not a necessary condition for <strong>the</strong> lending view, afinding <strong>of</strong> significant credit rationing would support <strong>the</strong> lending view.Empirical evidence relating to <strong>the</strong> credit rationing channel has been extensively presented butfrom many different perspectives. In general, however, three areas <strong>of</strong> research developmenthave been identified.<strong>The</strong> first group <strong>of</strong> researchers have emphasised <strong>the</strong> difference in <strong>the</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> equilibrium<strong>and</strong> disequilibrium credit rationing (Jaffee <strong>and</strong> Modigliani (1969); Fair <strong>and</strong> Jaffee (1972);Qu<strong>and</strong>t (1978); Bowden (1978); Sealey (1979); Ito <strong>and</strong> Ueda (1981); <strong>and</strong> Arndt (1982)).<strong>The</strong> second group <strong>of</strong> researchers have focused on credit rationing in <strong>the</strong> loan market withimperfect information between borrowers <strong>and</strong> lenders (Jaffee <strong>and</strong> Russell (1976); <strong>and</strong>Stiglitz <strong>and</strong> Weiss (1981 <strong>and</strong> 1990)).<strong>The</strong> final group have sought to find evidence <strong>of</strong> whe<strong>the</strong>r or not equilibrium credit rationingplays a significant macroeconomic role (King (1986); Montiel (1991); Blinder (1987);McCallum (1991); Yang (1994); <strong>and</strong> Ma <strong>and</strong> Smith (1996)).


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 28Previous studies by <strong>the</strong> first group <strong>of</strong> researchers concentrated mostly on <strong>the</strong> problemsassociated with estimating supply <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> schedules in disequilibrium markets. Among<strong>the</strong>m, Fair <strong>and</strong> Jaffee (1972), Maddala <strong>and</strong> Nelson (1974), <strong>and</strong> Fair <strong>and</strong> Kelejian (1974),for example, argued that <strong>the</strong> maximum likelihood approach is <strong>the</strong> appropriate method <strong>of</strong>estimation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> disequilibrium model. <strong>The</strong>ir base-line models are presented in Section 3.4.In exp<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>the</strong>se studies, Qu<strong>and</strong>t (1978) <strong>and</strong> Bowden (1978) developed a framework inorder for <strong>the</strong> equilibrium hypo<strong>the</strong>sis against <strong>the</strong> disequilibrium hypo<strong>the</strong>sis, to be tested usingonly one model. Based on <strong>the</strong>se developments in <strong>the</strong> literature, Sealey (1979) was among<strong>the</strong> first to estimate equilibrium vs. disequilibrium credit rationing in <strong>the</strong> commercial loanmarket using a reduced form <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> loan rate function. He argued that <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> creditrationing was simply due to <strong>the</strong> incomplete loan rate adjustment in a situation <strong>of</strong> excessdem<strong>and</strong> for loans. <strong>The</strong> results <strong>of</strong> estimation supported his hypo<strong>the</strong>sis.Following Bowden (1978), Ito <strong>and</strong> Ueda (1981) estimated <strong>the</strong> loan rate adjustment speedon <strong>the</strong> U.S. <strong>and</strong> Japanese data. <strong>The</strong>y found that <strong>the</strong> loan rate adjusted more slowly in Japanthan in <strong>the</strong> United States. This result confirmed <strong>the</strong> conjecture that <strong>the</strong> Japanese financialmarket, which is subject to more regulation, is fur<strong>the</strong>r away from equilibrium than <strong>the</strong> USmarket.<strong>The</strong> second group <strong>of</strong> researchers focused attention on credit rationing in <strong>the</strong> loan marketwith imperfect information between borrowers <strong>and</strong> lenders. Two <strong>the</strong>oretical papers byJaffee <strong>and</strong> Modigliani (1969) <strong>and</strong> Stiglitz <strong>and</strong> Weiss (1981), are worth mentioning here.Both authors argued that <strong>the</strong> earlier studies <strong>of</strong> credit rationing concentrated only on <strong>the</strong>


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 29supply-side <strong>of</strong> loan while neglecting <strong>the</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>-side for loan <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> determinants <strong>of</strong>loan rate.In reality, banks face heterogeneous borrowers <strong>and</strong> banks are, <strong>the</strong>refore, concerned about<strong>the</strong> interest rates <strong>the</strong>y receive on <strong>the</strong> loan <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> riskiness <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> loan. Thus banks must sortpotential borrowers (<strong>the</strong> adverse selection effect) or affect <strong>the</strong> action <strong>of</strong> borrowers (<strong>the</strong>incentive effect).Stiglitz <strong>and</strong> Weiss (1981) argue “both effects derive directly from <strong>the</strong> residual imperfectinformation which is present in loan markets after banks have evaluated loan application.”<strong>The</strong>oretically, in a situation <strong>of</strong> an excess dem<strong>and</strong> for loans, deficit units are willing to paymore at <strong>the</strong> loan rate. But as banks want to maximise expected pr<strong>of</strong>it, such a loan is viewedas a risky loan, <strong>and</strong> thus credit is rationed. Based on this proposition, <strong>the</strong>ir models assume<strong>the</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> for a loan is a function <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> loan rate alone, while <strong>the</strong> loan supply is a function<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> maximised expected pr<strong>of</strong>it, which in turn is a function <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> loan rate <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> loanrisk.However, <strong>the</strong>se assumptions also subjected to criticism. For example, as argued by Yang(1994), this is similar to saying that <strong>the</strong> loan rate is <strong>the</strong> only decision variable <strong>and</strong> isdetermined solely by <strong>the</strong> lending bank. As a result, in reality <strong>the</strong>ir assumption is alsoquestionable because <strong>the</strong> loan market is competitive in nature (in <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> governmentcontrol) <strong>and</strong> is determined by both <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> sides.


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 30Recent development <strong>of</strong> literature has extended <strong>the</strong> Stiglitz <strong>and</strong> Weiss framework todetermine whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> credit rationing phenomenon is <strong>of</strong> macroeconomic importance.Hence, more recent studies by <strong>the</strong> third group <strong>of</strong> researchers have attempted to findevidence regarding <strong>the</strong> relationship between bank credit aggregate <strong>and</strong> macroeconomicvariables. See, for example, studies conducted by King (1986); Blinder (1987); McCallum(1991); Yang (1994); <strong>and</strong> Ma <strong>and</strong> Smith (1996).King (1986) constructed a simple partial equilibrium model <strong>of</strong> bank behaviour to analyse <strong>the</strong>possibility <strong>and</strong> implications <strong>of</strong> equilibrium credit rationing. His model assumed banksoperate in three markets, namely <strong>the</strong> loan market, deposit market <strong>and</strong> securities market.<strong>The</strong> model allows <strong>the</strong> log <strong>of</strong> real loan dem<strong>and</strong> to depend on <strong>the</strong> loan rate, <strong>the</strong> rate oncommercial paper, <strong>the</strong> expected inflation rate, <strong>the</strong> log <strong>of</strong> GNP, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> lagged quantity <strong>of</strong>loans. Loan supply is assumed to depend on <strong>the</strong> loan <strong>and</strong> mortgage rates, <strong>the</strong> expectedinflation rate, a time trend, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> log dem<strong>and</strong> deposits. <strong>The</strong> results <strong>of</strong> estimation show that<strong>the</strong> loan supply is responsive to <strong>the</strong> loan rate <strong>and</strong> thus in contradiction to <strong>the</strong> equilibriumrationing hypo<strong>the</strong>sis. In addition, his findings indicate that nei<strong>the</strong>r commercial <strong>and</strong> industrialloans nor total bank loans significantly help output prediction in ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> whole sample orany subperiod.In contrast, McCallum (1991) showed that <strong>the</strong> credit rationing mechanism did not only exist,but was also important - it accounted for about half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total contribution <strong>of</strong> monetaryshocks to fluctuations in GNP. <strong>The</strong> estimated model was based on Blinder’s (1987)framework. Three credit rationing proxies were used. <strong>The</strong> first proxy used was <strong>the</strong> excess


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 31dem<strong>and</strong> for commercial loans estimated by King (1986). <strong>The</strong> second proxy used wasvarious credit crunch periods based on <strong>the</strong> work <strong>of</strong> Eckstein (1983) <strong>and</strong> Sinai (1976). <strong>The</strong>third proxy used was <strong>the</strong> detrended growth rate <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> actual money supply (M1 <strong>and</strong> M2).Recently, Yang (1994) proposed ano<strong>the</strong>r credit rationing proxy, i.e. <strong>the</strong> quarterly surveydata <strong>of</strong> small firms on <strong>the</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> for loan. He argued that using this proxy is morerepresentative than <strong>the</strong> previous proxies because small firms are more vulnerable to creditrationing. O<strong>the</strong>r proxies used were <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> bank loans to <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> bank loans <strong>and</strong>commercial paper outst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> banks’ commercial <strong>and</strong> industrial loans tosmall <strong>and</strong> large firms. Using <strong>the</strong> multivariate VAR, his finding supported <strong>the</strong> hypo<strong>the</strong>sis that<strong>the</strong>re was an important credit rationing channel, <strong>and</strong> in fact it had greater residualexplanatory power in predicting <strong>the</strong> output than did <strong>the</strong> money channel.3.3.3 Evidence from <strong>the</strong> Developing Countries Relating to <strong>the</strong> Credit ChannelSo far, empirical evidence regarding <strong>the</strong> credit channel in developing countries is verydifficult to find. See, Table 3.2 below. However, three most recent studies by Scholnick(1991a, 1991b), Tan (1995), <strong>and</strong> Demetriades <strong>and</strong> Luintel (1996) 12 , are worth noting.Scholnick (1991a, 1991b) <strong>and</strong> Tan (1995) 13 tested a disequilibrium model <strong>of</strong> lending ratedetermination using <strong>the</strong> Malaysian data. Both studies employed <strong>the</strong> Stiglitz <strong>and</strong> Weiss’s(1981) base-line model. Using <strong>the</strong> error-correction-mechanism specification, Scholnick’12 <strong>The</strong> study by Demetriades <strong>and</strong> Luintel (1996) actually examined <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> various types <strong>of</strong>banking sector controls on <strong>the</strong> process <strong>of</strong> financial deepening. Using <strong>the</strong> Indian data, <strong>the</strong>y found that,‘with <strong>the</strong> exception <strong>of</strong> a lending rate ceiling, <strong>the</strong>se control are found to influence financial deepeningnegetively...Exogeneity tests suggest that financial deepening <strong>and</strong> economic growth are jointly


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 32study showed that <strong>the</strong> lending rate did not fully clear <strong>the</strong> loan market. This indicated that<strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> credit rationing was due to <strong>the</strong> slow adjustment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> loan rate. Similarevidence has also been portrayed by Tan (1995).Unfortunately, both <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> above studies did not attempt to explain whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> creditrationing phenomenon had any macroeconomic importance relating to <strong>the</strong> Malaysianeconomy. Moreover, <strong>the</strong>se studies did not investigate whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>re was any relationshipbetween <strong>the</strong> monetary policy, credit <strong>and</strong> economic activity during <strong>the</strong> pre- <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> postliberalisationperiods. <strong>The</strong>se studies also did not test whe<strong>the</strong>r or not banks act in aggregateto rationing credit. Thus, whe<strong>the</strong>r bank credit was an important channel <strong>of</strong> transmissionmechanism in <strong>the</strong> Malaysian economy was left to be answered. To answer this question,this is one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> main tasks <strong>of</strong> this <strong>the</strong>sis which shares <strong>the</strong> current mainstream research focuson <strong>the</strong> credit view.determined. Thus, policies which affect financial deepening may also have an influence on economicgrowth.’13 Scholnick (1991a, 1991b) <strong>and</strong> Tan (1995) estimated <strong>the</strong>ir model using <strong>the</strong> error-correction mechanism.


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 33Table 3.2: Selected Empirical Studies On Developing Countriesauthor (year)Barry Scholnick(1991a)Eu Chye Tan(1995)country/datafrequencyMalaysiamonthly data1985:1 - 1990:12Malaysiaquarterly data1979:I - 1991:IVmodel / method <strong>of</strong> estimation variables used findings‘Stiglitz- Weiss’ CreditrationingModel (1981)Lending rate adjustmentequation based on Stiglitz-Weiss’ Credit-rationing Model(1981)interbank rate; lending rate;deposit rate;total loans <strong>and</strong> advancesextended by commercial banks;average lending rate levied bycommercial banks, 3-monthTBR; UK TBR; Total deposits;excess liquidity ratio; capital<strong>and</strong> reserves <strong>of</strong> commercialbanks as a proportion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>irassets/liabilities.This study estimates a disequilibrium model <strong>of</strong>lending rate determination in Malaysia. <strong>The</strong>results <strong>of</strong> estimation support <strong>the</strong> evidence <strong>of</strong>disequilibrium in loan market.Loan rate appears to respond only neglibly to loansupply factors, while not a single loan dem<strong>and</strong>factor appears to have influenced it. Inspite <strong>of</strong>financial liberalization, one may conclude thatequilibrium credit rationing could prevail in <strong>the</strong>Malaysian financial system.


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 353.4 Disequilibrium vs. Equilibrium Credit Rationing Models for Bank Loans<strong>The</strong> question <strong>of</strong> credit rationing models for bank loans has been <strong>the</strong> subject <strong>of</strong> a number <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong>oretical discussions during <strong>the</strong> past decades. It is generally accepted that credit rationingoccurs if <strong>the</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> for loans exceeds <strong>the</strong> supply at <strong>the</strong> prevailing price.In <strong>the</strong> credit rationing literature, <strong>the</strong> credit rationing phenomenon is broadly categorised intodisequilibrium credit rationing (DCR) <strong>and</strong> equilibrium credit rationing (ECR). <strong>The</strong> DCR is ashort-run phenomenon caused by <strong>the</strong> loan rate stickiness or by institutional constraints suchas government setting <strong>the</strong> credit limits or regulations which control <strong>the</strong> limit on interest rates((Roosa (1951) <strong>and</strong> Guttentag (1960)). In a different perspective, Arndt (1982) suggestedthat <strong>the</strong> definition <strong>of</strong> disequilibrium credit rationing refers only to “government rationing”<strong>of</strong> credit. His examples <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> DCR measurements include interest-rate control <strong>and</strong> directquantitative limits placed on lending institutions. For example, <strong>the</strong> imposition <strong>of</strong> interest-ratecontrols, will lead to an excess dem<strong>and</strong> for credit to <strong>the</strong> extent that <strong>the</strong> loans are maintainedbelow <strong>the</strong> market-clearing level. <strong>The</strong>refore, interest rate ceilings will lead to temporary orshort-run deviations from <strong>the</strong> equilibrium point.<strong>The</strong> equilibrium credit rationing (ECR) phenomenon is caused by <strong>the</strong> non-price factors.Again, using Arndt’s terminology, <strong>the</strong> ECR is apparently caused by “bank rationing” <strong>of</strong>credit. Only recently, <strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard definition <strong>of</strong> ECR has been referred by Jaffee <strong>and</strong>Russell (1976) <strong>and</strong> Stiglitz <strong>and</strong> Weiss (1981) as due to ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> imperfect informationbetween borrowers <strong>and</strong> lenders or to non-price factors.


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 36Within <strong>the</strong> scope <strong>of</strong> this <strong>the</strong>sis, <strong>the</strong> Arndt (1982) definition <strong>of</strong> ‘disequilibrium creditrationing’ is interchangeably used for <strong>the</strong> exogenous credit rationing; <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> definition <strong>of</strong>‘equilibrium credit rationing’ by Jaffee <strong>and</strong> Russell (1976) <strong>and</strong> Stiglitz <strong>and</strong> Weiss (1981)is interchangeably used for <strong>the</strong> endogenous credit rationing.<strong>The</strong> empirical evidence relating to <strong>the</strong> credit rationing channel has been discussed in Section3.3.2. In <strong>the</strong> subsequent section, <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>oretical models <strong>of</strong> equilibrium vs. disequilibriumcredit rationing are presented.3.4.1 Equilibrium vs. Disequilibrium Credit Rationing ModelsFollowing a seminal paper by Fair <strong>and</strong> Jaffee (1972), many authors developed methods <strong>of</strong>estimation for market disequilibrium vs. equilibrium. <strong>The</strong>se included. among o<strong>the</strong>rs, studiesby Fair <strong>and</strong> Kelejian (1974), Maddala <strong>and</strong> Nelson (1974), Qu<strong>and</strong>t (1978), <strong>and</strong> Bowden(1978) 14 . Applications <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se models to <strong>the</strong> loan market have been conducted by Sealey(1979), Ito <strong>and</strong> Ueda (1981) <strong>and</strong> King (1986).Sealey (1979) <strong>and</strong> King (1986) adopted <strong>the</strong> Maddala <strong>and</strong> Nelson model (MN), while Ito<strong>and</strong> Ueda (1981) used <strong>the</strong> Bowden model (BO). <strong>The</strong>se models are described below.14 Multimarket models with disequilibrium were proposed by Ito (1980), <strong>and</strong> Gourieroux, Laffont <strong>and</strong>Monfort (1980).


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 373.4.1.1 <strong>The</strong> Maddala <strong>and</strong> Nelson Model<strong>The</strong> Maddala <strong>and</strong> Nelson’s model consists <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> following equations:= β + β + µ (3.26)D Lt rLt 1 X1t 2 1t= β + β + µ (3.27)S Lt rLt 3 X2 t 4 2tQLt= min( , ) (3.28)DtSt∆ r Lt = γ D t − S t + µt( ) ; 0 ≤ γ ≤ ∞(3.29)3where D L <strong>and</strong> S L are <strong>the</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> for <strong>and</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> loans, respectively; Q L t is <strong>the</strong> observedquantity; r Lt is <strong>the</strong> loan rate; X 1t <strong>and</strong> X 2t are vectors <strong>of</strong> exogenous variables; <strong>and</strong> µ 1t , µ 2t <strong>and</strong>µ 3t are error terms.In <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> market clearing conditions, D t = S t = Q t , equations (3.28) <strong>and</strong> (3.29) will<strong>the</strong>refore be eliminated. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>the</strong> occurrence <strong>of</strong> any disequilibrium such ascredit rationing will lead to incomplete price adjustment. <strong>The</strong>refore, any divergence betweenquantity dem<strong>and</strong>ed <strong>and</strong> supplied will be captured by equations (3.28) <strong>and</strong> (3.29).Particularly, equation (3.29) captures <strong>the</strong> price adjustment process. Thus, as suggested bySealey (1979), <strong>the</strong> above model measure <strong>the</strong> dynamic effects <strong>of</strong> rationing, i.e. <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong>rationing during <strong>the</strong> adjustment process. Two testable hypo<strong>the</strong>ses from this model include:Hypo<strong>the</strong>sis 1: H o : γ = 0;[γ = 0 to indicate no price adjustment in response to excess dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>reforeto indicate <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> disequilibrium credit rationing].Hypo<strong>the</strong>sis 2: H o : γ = ∞;


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 38[γ = ∞ to indicate instantaneous price adjustment in response to market dem<strong>and</strong><strong>and</strong> supply <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>refore to indicate <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> an equilibrium market].3.4.1.2 <strong>The</strong> Bowden ModelBowden’s model consists <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> following equations:= α + α +(3.30)L 'DtXt 1 2Pt u1t= β + β +(3.31)L 'StZt 1 2 Pt u 2tQLt= min( , ) (3.32){DtStP = µ P + ( 1- µ ) P }; 0 £ µ £ 1;if P > P*t 1 t -1 1 t 1 t t -1{*t 2 t -1 2 t 2 t t -1(3.33a)P = { µ P + ( 1- µ ) P }; 0 £ µ £ 1;if P > P(3.33b)where D <strong>and</strong> S are <strong>the</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> for <strong>and</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> loans, respectively, which are notnecessarily observable; Q is <strong>the</strong> observed level <strong>of</strong> transactions; X’ <strong>and</strong> Z’ are vectors <strong>of</strong>predetermined variables; P t is <strong>the</strong> loan rate; <strong>and</strong> µ 1t , µ 2t are error terms - where µ 1 <strong>and</strong> µ 2represent <strong>the</strong> upward <strong>and</strong> downward price adjustments, respectively.To determine whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> loan rate is in equilibrium or o<strong>the</strong>rwise, <strong>the</strong> null hypo<strong>the</strong>sis µ 1 = µ 2=0 is tested. Acceptance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> null hypo<strong>the</strong>sis suggests <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> an equilibriummarket, o<strong>the</strong>rwise, it indicates <strong>the</strong> sluggishness <strong>of</strong> price movements as shown by equations(3.33a) <strong>and</strong> (3.33b).


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 39A reduced form <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> loan rate equation (P t *) is derived by first equating (3.30) <strong>and</strong>(3.31) in terms <strong>of</strong> exogenous variables <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> error term. Second, by substituting into(3.33), yields' 'Pt = µ Pt −1 + θ( Xt α 1− Zt β ) + θ( u t −1 1 u 2t)(3.34)where θ = ( 1− µ ) / ( β − α )2 2If <strong>the</strong> ordinary least square (OLS) result provides serially uncorrelated error terms, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>equilibrium hypo<strong>the</strong>sis can be easily tested by using <strong>the</strong> t-test on <strong>the</strong> µ.According to Ito <strong>and</strong> Ueda (1981), <strong>and</strong> also claimed by Bowden (1978), <strong>the</strong> Bowdenmodel has two advantages compared to <strong>the</strong> Maddala-Nelson model. Firstly, <strong>the</strong> equilibriumhypo<strong>the</strong>sis <strong>of</strong> µ= 0 can be easily tested in <strong>the</strong> Bowden model as shown by equations(3.33a) -(3.33b). Secondly, as Ito <strong>and</strong> Ueda (1981; p.694) argue “...<strong>the</strong> parameter µ isunit-free in <strong>the</strong> Bowden model, leading itself to cross-market comparisons. Thus, <strong>the</strong>Bowden model specifications can capture <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> disequilibrium across <strong>the</strong> markets.On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r h<strong>and</strong>, γ (in equation 3.29 <strong>of</strong> Maddala-Nelson’s model) is measured in units <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> price (index) in terms <strong>of</strong> units <strong>of</strong> quantity. Thus, it is not always possible to compareestimated γ‘s for different markets.”


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 403.5 <strong>The</strong> Relevance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Credit Rationing Channel in MalaysiaDuring <strong>the</strong> pre-liberalisation period, <strong>the</strong> monetary authority implemented various measures tocontrol <strong>the</strong> loan market, namely <strong>the</strong> reserve requirements, a ceiling on <strong>the</strong> loan rate, a flooron <strong>the</strong> deposit rate <strong>and</strong> directed credit programmes with a lower lending rate. <strong>The</strong>refore,<strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> exogenous credit rationing channel during <strong>the</strong> pre-liberalisation periodwas straightfowardly evident.Although <strong>the</strong> domestic interest rates were liberalised after 1979, <strong>the</strong>re were several eventsthat led to interest rate market distortions. For example, in 1981, <strong>the</strong> Malaysian Association<strong>of</strong> Commercial Banks introduced <strong>the</strong> base lending rate (BLR) among its members. <strong>The</strong>n, in1987 <strong>the</strong> Central Bank took over <strong>the</strong> administration <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> BLR. However, in 1991, <strong>the</strong>BLR was abolished to allow <strong>the</strong> commercial banks to determine <strong>the</strong> loan rate in a morecompetitive environment. Thus, this study hypo<strong>the</strong>sises <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> endogenous creditrationing channel in <strong>the</strong> Malaysian loan market during <strong>the</strong> post-liberalisation period.<strong>The</strong> question to be asked is why is exogenous/disequilibrium credit rationing bad for <strong>the</strong>banking institution. As we know, <strong>the</strong> control measure sets <strong>the</strong> loan rate below <strong>the</strong> marketclearinglevel. (Consider Figure 3.2 below). In a competitive credit market environment,<strong>the</strong> banks face an upward sloping supply curve <strong>of</strong> deposit (S D ). For a given supply curve <strong>of</strong>deposits, plus o<strong>the</strong>r costs (i.e. management’s cost, interest margin), <strong>the</strong> bank’s loan supplycurve is S L . <strong>The</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> curve for loans is given by L D . In equilibrium, <strong>the</strong> volume <strong>of</strong>deposits <strong>and</strong> loans is OL 1 . <strong>The</strong> banks pay a deposit rate <strong>of</strong> i D <strong>and</strong> charge a loan rate <strong>of</strong> i L .Thus, <strong>the</strong> bank’s margin <strong>of</strong> interest is i L -i D . In turn, consider <strong>the</strong> disequilibrium credit


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 41rationing situation, i.e. when <strong>the</strong> Central Bank imposes both a ceiling on <strong>the</strong> loan rate <strong>and</strong>a floor on <strong>the</strong> deposit rate. For practical purposes <strong>the</strong> monopoly case is certainly closer to<strong>the</strong> oligopolistic situations that describe reality in developing countries (Courakis, 1984).Imposing a floor on <strong>the</strong> deposit rate ( i D) attracts more deposits, while a ceiling on <strong>the</strong> loanrate ( i L) provides more loans to <strong>the</strong> deficit units. Because <strong>the</strong> commercial banks areheavily regulated, <strong>the</strong>y have no o<strong>the</strong>r choice but to obey <strong>the</strong> Central Bank’s instruction.Thus, Figure 3.2 can be modified to illustrate <strong>the</strong> effect <strong>of</strong> imposing both constraints on <strong>the</strong>commercial banks.In Figure 3.3, we add <strong>the</strong> marginal cost curve (MC) <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> marginal revenue curve (MR).Thus, <strong>the</strong> Figure clearly shows that more loans can be extended in <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> bothconstraints L , compared to <strong>the</strong> volume <strong>of</strong> loans under competition L 1 .


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 42rate <strong>of</strong>interesti Li Di DL 1rate <strong>of</strong>interesti LiLiDFigure 3.2: Competitive Credit MarketL 1E 1L DLoan/DepositE 1S L S D S DLFigure 3.3: Credit Rationing MarketMRMCL DLoan/Deposit


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 433.6 Statement <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Research Problems<strong>The</strong> survey <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> empirical literature shows a number <strong>of</strong> interesting issues relating to <strong>the</strong>country-coverage, <strong>the</strong> choice <strong>of</strong> data <strong>and</strong> methodology, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> evidence from previouswork. <strong>The</strong>refore, <strong>the</strong> direction <strong>of</strong> this <strong>the</strong>sis will pay attention to <strong>the</strong> following issues.First, <strong>the</strong> evidence from developing economies has received very little attention in <strong>the</strong>literature. Two previous studies on Malaysia did not attempt to explain whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> creditrationing phenomenon had any macroeconomic importance to <strong>the</strong> economy in question. Inaddition, both studies failed to investigate whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>re is any relationship betweenmonetary policy, credit, <strong>and</strong> economic activity during <strong>the</strong> pre-liberalisation <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> postliberalisationperiods. <strong>The</strong>refore, whe<strong>the</strong>r money or credit, or both are an important channel<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> transmission mechanism process remains to be tested.Second, <strong>the</strong> survey has shown <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> choosing an appropriate methodology <strong>and</strong>data set. <strong>The</strong> evidence from <strong>the</strong> industrialised countries has shown that whe<strong>the</strong>r usingaggregate data or disaggregated data, <strong>the</strong> results are at best mixed. <strong>The</strong>refore, <strong>the</strong>important point is to pay attention to whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> data are relevant to <strong>the</strong> economic <strong>the</strong>ory.Moreover, recent literature also suggests <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> testing <strong>the</strong> time series properties.Third, most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> previous studies have employed <strong>the</strong> VAR methodology. See, Table 3.1<strong>and</strong> Table 3.2. Some researchers have used unrestricted VAR, while o<strong>the</strong>rs have usedrestricted VAR. However, as argued by Bernanke <strong>and</strong> Blinder (1992, p. 901), “..it isextremely risky to make structural inferences from unrestricted VAR, which after all are only


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 44reduced forms. If we want to measure <strong>the</strong> true structural effects <strong>of</strong> a policy change,<strong>the</strong>re are only two alternatives.” First, we can specify <strong>and</strong> estimate a structural economicmodel, such as <strong>the</strong> restricted structural VAR model employed by Bernanke (1986). <strong>The</strong>second alternative is to find a proper measure <strong>of</strong> monetary policy variables. Thus, <strong>the</strong>chosen variables must have a good reduced-form predictor <strong>of</strong> major macroeconomicactivities (Bernanke <strong>and</strong> Blinder, 1992, pp. 902-903). <strong>The</strong>se issues are considered in this<strong>the</strong>sis.<strong>The</strong> fourth issue is <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> monetary policy reaction function. As argued byTaylor (1995, p. 15), “a complete story <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> monetary transmission mechanism shouldthus include a description <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Central Bank’s reaction function showing how <strong>the</strong> CentralBank adjusts <strong>the</strong> [monetary policy variables] in response to various factors in <strong>the</strong> economy,including real GDP <strong>and</strong> inflation.” With <strong>the</strong> exception <strong>of</strong> Bernanke <strong>and</strong> Blinder (1992),most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> previous studies in this area have ignored this aspect. As stressed by Bernanke<strong>and</strong> Blinder (1992), if one has selected well <strong>the</strong> measure <strong>of</strong> monetary policy, <strong>the</strong>n it must beable to respond to <strong>the</strong> Central Bank’s reaction <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> state <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy. In <strong>the</strong> context<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Malaysian economy, financial liberalisation has certainly changed <strong>the</strong> enviroment inwhich monetary policy operates. Thus <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se factors on <strong>the</strong> domestic economyneed to be taken into account.3.7 Concluding RemarksThis chapter has provided a review <strong>of</strong> literature on <strong>the</strong> transmission mechanism process <strong>and</strong><strong>the</strong> channels <strong>of</strong> monetary policy. As discussed, <strong>the</strong> survey has uncovered much interesting


@ Free Notes by Dr. Azali Mohamed 45evidence relating to country-coverage, data, methodology <strong>and</strong> findings <strong>of</strong> previous work.<strong>The</strong> evidence has been used to develop <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>sis’s research direction as discussed inSection 3.6.In addition, <strong>the</strong> survey also showed that efforts to investigate <strong>the</strong> channels <strong>of</strong> monetarytransmission can be divided into two categories (Cacchetti, 1995). <strong>The</strong>y are:• Studies look at <strong>the</strong> relative forecasting ability <strong>of</strong> quantity aggregates relating to money <strong>and</strong>credit. <strong>The</strong> methodology is <strong>the</strong>n to ask whe<strong>the</strong>r measures <strong>of</strong> money or credit areinformative about future output movements.• Studies focus to <strong>the</strong> differences in <strong>the</strong> timing <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> response <strong>of</strong> output to presumed policyshocks. <strong>The</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard features <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> methodology looking at impulse responses <strong>and</strong>variance decompositions whe<strong>the</strong>r output responds differently to money or creditinnovations.Having discussed <strong>the</strong>se aspects, <strong>the</strong> forthcoming chapters investigate empirically <strong>the</strong> issues,<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> most immediate chapter investigates <strong>the</strong> time series properties <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> data.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!