11.07.2015 Views

Does it pay to pay teachers more? - The Association for Education ...

Does it pay to pay teachers more? - The Association for Education ...

Does it pay to pay teachers more? - The Association for Education ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Does</strong> <strong>it</strong> <strong>pay</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>pay</strong> <strong>teachers</strong> <strong>more</strong>? Evidence from Oklahoma’sminimum salary scheduleMatthew D. Hendricks ∗March 8, 2012DO NOT CITE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSIONAbstractSurprisingly l<strong>it</strong>tle is known about how teacher salaries are causally related <strong>to</strong> educationqual<strong>it</strong>y. Conventional wisdom suggests that higher-<strong>pay</strong>ing districts will likely operate <strong>more</strong>efficiently by reducing teacher turnover. In add<strong>it</strong>ion, standard theories in labor economicssuggest that higher wages may provide an incentive <strong>for</strong> <strong>teachers</strong> <strong>to</strong> work harder and may allowdistricts <strong>to</strong> attract and retain better <strong>teachers</strong>. While the potential <strong>for</strong> a relationship exists, priorempirical research has not generally supported the hypothesis that higher teacher <strong>pay</strong> bringsthe benef<strong>it</strong> of improved education qual<strong>it</strong>y. In this study I revis<strong>it</strong> this question w<strong>it</strong>h the benef<strong>it</strong>of <strong>more</strong> detailed data and a <strong>more</strong> robust estimation strategy.Public education is expensive. Each year in the Un<strong>it</strong>ed States federal, state, and local governmentsdole out billions of dollars <strong>to</strong> fund education. For the 2009-010 school year the NationalCenter <strong>for</strong> <strong>Education</strong> Statistics projects that about $602 billion was spent <strong>to</strong> support public elementaryand secondary schools (Snyder & Dillow 2011). <strong>The</strong> financial burden is particularly highat the local and state levels, which provide about 43.5% and 48.3% percent of funds respectively(Snyder & Dillow 2011). In <strong>to</strong>tal, state and local governments allocate about a quarter of theircombined budgets <strong>to</strong> support public K-12 education (Snyder & Dillow 2011).While education funding accounts <strong>for</strong> a large proportion of public dollars spent, especially atthe state and local levels, l<strong>it</strong>tle is known about how education funding and allocations are related<strong>to</strong> education qual<strong>it</strong>y. In particular, surprisingly l<strong>it</strong>tle is known about how teacher’s salaries impactqual<strong>it</strong>y, desp<strong>it</strong>e the fact that teacher’s salaries account <strong>for</strong> about 35% of current K-12 funding∗ <strong>The</strong> Univers<strong>it</strong>y of Tulsa, 800 South Tucker Drive Tulsa OK 74104, matthew-hendricks@utulsa.edu.1


(Snyder & Dillow 2011). Conventional wisdom suggests that districts that <strong>pay</strong> <strong>more</strong> will likelyattract and retain better <strong>teachers</strong>. However, prior research has not clearly supported this idea. Par<strong>to</strong>f the explanation <strong>for</strong> the lack of clar<strong>it</strong>y stems from the fact that <strong>it</strong> is difficult <strong>to</strong> estimate the causaleffect of teacher salaries on education qual<strong>it</strong>y. In order <strong>to</strong> estimate this causal relationship onemust adequately control <strong>for</strong> fac<strong>to</strong>rs that influence education qual<strong>it</strong>y and are correlated w<strong>it</strong>h <strong>teachers</strong>alaries, which is not easily accomplished in observational studies.Given the size of the public investment and stakes involved in improving the qual<strong>it</strong>y of education,we ought <strong>to</strong> know whether current teacher salaries are ideal or can be altered in some way thatcan improve qual<strong>it</strong>y. If administra<strong>to</strong>rs moved funds away from teacher salaries and in<strong>to</strong> other areas,such as administra<strong>to</strong>r salaries, books, computers, and facil<strong>it</strong>ies, would qual<strong>it</strong>y improve? Alternatively,might teacher salaries be <strong>to</strong>o low? That is, would increasing teacher salaries at the expenseof other areas of education finance cause overall qual<strong>it</strong>y <strong>to</strong> improve? <strong>The</strong>se are important policyquestions that we can begin <strong>to</strong> answer if we measure the relationship between teacher salaries andeducation qual<strong>it</strong>y.Using a robust estimation strategy that relies on detailed district data and state-imposed variationin teacher salary, this study aims <strong>to</strong> measure the causal effect of public school teacher salarieson the qual<strong>it</strong>y of public education. I estimate the effect of teacher salaries in Oklahoma on the followingdistrict-level outcome measures: average student test scores, student drop-out rates, annualteacher turnover rates, and the characteristics of new teacher hires.Preliminary results suggest that large increases in Oklahoma’s state minimum teacher salaryschedule in 2007 and 2008 significantly reduced teacher turnover. <strong>The</strong>se results are preliminary.Please do not c<strong>it</strong>e w<strong>it</strong>hout author’s permission.This work is organized as follows: section 1 provides a brief review of the l<strong>it</strong>erature; section2 discusses the theoretical linkage between teacher <strong>pay</strong> and teacher qual<strong>it</strong>y; section 3 details theempirical model and describes the data; section 4 presents the results; section 5 discusses theimplications of the findings.2


1 L<strong>it</strong>erature review<strong>The</strong>re are several strands of l<strong>it</strong>erature that are relevant <strong>to</strong> this research. One strand asks whether<strong>teachers</strong> matter. <strong>The</strong> question is whether kids who are assigned <strong>to</strong> a poor teacher per<strong>for</strong>m worsethan kids assigned <strong>to</strong> a good teacher. <strong>The</strong> answer <strong>to</strong> this question seems obvious, but only recentlyhave researchers been able <strong>to</strong> objectively measure variation in teacher per<strong>for</strong>mance. Several studieshave confirmed that there is significant variation in teacher effectiveness, where effectiveness ismeasured by the teacher’s average contribution <strong>to</strong> student achievement growth (Hanushek & Rivkin2010, Rockoff 2004, Kane & Staiger 2008, Rothstein 2010, Kane, Rockoff & Staiger 2008, Jacob& Lefgren 2008). <strong>The</strong>se studies suggest that there may be significant variation in teacher qual<strong>it</strong>y,even w<strong>it</strong>hin a school.Given the potentially large dispar<strong>it</strong>y between effective and poor <strong>teachers</strong>, another strand ofl<strong>it</strong>erature asks how districts or schools might attract the best <strong>teachers</strong>. An obvious policy instrumentis teacher salary. Holding all else constant, one might expect that if a district increases <strong>teachers</strong>alaries, then <strong>it</strong> might attract higher-abil<strong>it</strong>y individuals who might have otherwise chosen a higher<strong>pay</strong>ingprofession outside of teaching or a pos<strong>it</strong>ion at a competing district. This logic motivates thisresearch and has been the motivation behind other similar studies that attempt <strong>to</strong> find a relationshipbetween teacher <strong>pay</strong> and student outcomes.In this area, direct evidence of a link between teacher <strong>pay</strong> and student achievement is mixed.Loeb & Page (2000) find evidence that increased teacher salaries cause a reduction in studentdropout rates and an increase in college enrollment. However, Hanushek et al. (2005) find noevidence that higher-<strong>pay</strong>ing districts are able <strong>to</strong> attract and hire the best <strong>teachers</strong> away from otherlow-<strong>pay</strong>ing districts. In a survey of the l<strong>it</strong>erature prior <strong>to</strong> 1995, Hanushek et al. (2004) show tha<strong>to</strong>ut of 118 estimates of the relationship between teacher salaries and student achievement, only20% were pos<strong>it</strong>ive and significant, 7% were negative and significant, and 73% were insignificant.Out of the subset of student-level value-added estimates, where the analysis was restricted <strong>to</strong> asingle state, the evidence reported by Hanushek et al. (2004) is still weak: out of 17 estimates,only 3 reported a pos<strong>it</strong>ive and statistically significant relationship between teacher salaries and3


student achievement. In all, there is l<strong>it</strong>tle prior evidence linking teacher salaries directly <strong>to</strong> studentachievement.Another strand of l<strong>it</strong>erature has had success in establishing indirect links between teacher <strong>pay</strong>and student outcomes. For example, evidence suggests that that higher teacher <strong>pay</strong> can reduceteacher turnover (Clotfelter et al. 2008, Hanushek, Kain & Rivkin 2004), which can improve studen<strong>to</strong>utcomes (Ronfeldt et al. 2011). In add<strong>it</strong>ion, reduced teacher turnover can help the districtmaintain an experienced teaching staff, and there is strong evidence showing that experienced<strong>teachers</strong> have a larger pos<strong>it</strong>ive effect on student achievement than <strong>teachers</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h fewer than threeyears of experience (Rockoff 2004, Hanushek & Rivkin 2010, Staiger & Rockoff 2010).Overall, the l<strong>it</strong>erature suggests that <strong>teachers</strong> are important and that there is significant variationin qual<strong>it</strong>y among <strong>teachers</strong>, even w<strong>it</strong>hin a given school. However, the evidence supporting the notionthat increasing teacher <strong>pay</strong> will attract better <strong>teachers</strong> and improve education qual<strong>it</strong>y is weak,particularly where studies look <strong>for</strong> a direct link between teacher <strong>pay</strong> and student outcomes. Asimple explanation <strong>for</strong> these results may be that a causal relationship simply does not exist. However,the presence of econometric complications in prior studies motivates this author <strong>to</strong> reexaminethis question. Most of the prior studies that examine the link between teacher salaries and studentachievement potentially suffer from bias caused by not properly controlling <strong>for</strong> local labor marketcharacteristics and nonpecuniary attributes of teaching (Loeb & Page 2000). In add<strong>it</strong>ion, mostprior studies fail <strong>to</strong> correct <strong>for</strong> potential correlation between salaries and unobservables that alsoinfluence student achievement, which can introduce add<strong>it</strong>ional bias.This study contributes <strong>to</strong> the l<strong>it</strong>erature by employing <strong>more</strong> detailed data than researchers havepreviously used in this area. In add<strong>it</strong>ion, I rely on state imposed teacher salary changes <strong>to</strong> estimatethe effect of salaries on a variety of outcomes. By using detailed disaggregated data I am betterable <strong>to</strong> control <strong>for</strong> local labor market characteristics through district fixed effects and countyleveleconomic indica<strong>to</strong>rs. Also, by explo<strong>it</strong>ing state-imposed and state-funded changes in <strong>teachers</strong>alaries, my estimates capture the effects of variation in teacher <strong>pay</strong> that is independent of local ordistrict level characteristics, which further reduces the potential <strong>for</strong> bias.4


2 <strong>The</strong>oryChanges in teacher <strong>pay</strong> are likely <strong>to</strong> affect education qual<strong>it</strong>y though two mechanisms: by influencingthe efficiency of the school or district and by affecting teacher qual<strong>it</strong>y. W<strong>it</strong>h regard <strong>to</strong> the<strong>for</strong>mer case, intu<strong>it</strong>ion suggests that higher teacher <strong>pay</strong> may improve the efficiency of schools byreducing teacher turnover. Ronfeldt et al. (2011) suggest that teacher turnover can have a disruptiveimpact on student achievement by diverting district resources <strong>to</strong> the hiring process, weakeningteacher collaboration, and eroding the bond or level of trust between students and <strong>teachers</strong>. Basicintu<strong>it</strong>ion suggests that increases in teacher salary could have an immediate negative impact onteacher turnover, thereby increasing a school’s efficiency.W<strong>it</strong>h regard <strong>to</strong> the effect of teacher <strong>pay</strong> on teacher qual<strong>it</strong>y, standard theories in labor economicspredict both short and long-term effects. Efficiency wage theory describes a potential <strong>for</strong> a shorttermor immediate effects. According <strong>to</strong> efficiency wage theory, increases in wages can induce aworker <strong>to</strong> exert <strong>more</strong> ef<strong>for</strong>t. <strong>The</strong> efficiency wage model presented by Shapiro & Stigl<strong>it</strong>z (1984)suggests that when wages increase workers have an incentive <strong>to</strong> put <strong>for</strong>th <strong>more</strong> ef<strong>for</strong>t where thereis a threat of being fired. Alternatively, <strong>pay</strong>ing higher wages might increase worker productiv<strong>it</strong>y byincreasing morale (Akerlof 1982). Consistent w<strong>it</strong>h Shapiro & Stigl<strong>it</strong>z (1984), this short term effectshould be larger <strong>for</strong> untenured <strong>teachers</strong> where there is a greater threat of termination. However, ifthe teacher labor market is consistent w<strong>it</strong>h Akerlof (1982), then increased teacher salaries shouldinduce a generalized increase in teacher ef<strong>for</strong>t and qual<strong>it</strong>y in the short term.<strong>The</strong> long-term effects of increasing teacher salaries stem from a change in the characteristicsof individuals who self-select in<strong>to</strong> the district or profession. All else constant, an increase inteacher salaries across the board will likely increase the relative appeal of the profession, andincreases in salaries at the district level will increase the relative appeal of the district. <strong>The</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e,districts offering higher salaries are likely <strong>to</strong> attract <strong>more</strong> <strong>teachers</strong> from the upper tail of the abil<strong>it</strong>ydistribution. Likewise, a general increase in teacher salaries will likely attract <strong>more</strong> able individuals<strong>to</strong> the profession.This result follows from a standard Roy model of occupational choice (Roy 1951). To see this,5


assume there are two occupations: workers can work in e<strong>it</strong>her the private sec<strong>to</strong>r or can becomea public school teacher. Assume that workers possess two types of attributes: abil<strong>it</strong>y (a) andcredentials such as years of experience and years of schooling (c). Assume, as in the standard Roymodel, that these attributes are log-normally distributed in the population and may be correlated.Finally, <strong>pay</strong> in the two occupations is a function of the workers’ skills. In the private sec<strong>to</strong>r, workersare paid based on their abil<strong>it</strong>y (π 1 a) and public school <strong>teachers</strong> are paid a salary that is based on theworker’s credentials (π 2 c), where π 1 and π 1 are pos<strong>it</strong>ive constants. Workers choose the occupationthat provides them the highest salary given their skill endowments. In the “standard” 1 case of theRoy model, workers who self-select in<strong>to</strong> the private sec<strong>to</strong>r will have higher average abil<strong>it</strong>ies thanworkers who self-select in<strong>to</strong> the teaching profession (Heckman & Honor 1990). Teachers willhave better average credentials (experience and years of schooling) than the average worker in theprivate sec<strong>to</strong>r, but lower average abil<strong>it</strong>y.From this model, there are two major policy implications <strong>for</strong> improving the average abil<strong>it</strong>y of<strong>teachers</strong>. First, school districts can alter the way they <strong>pay</strong> <strong>teachers</strong>. Instead of <strong>pay</strong>ing teacher basedon their experience and education, they can <strong>pay</strong> <strong>teachers</strong> based on their abil<strong>it</strong>y. In other wordsschool districts can offer <strong>teachers</strong> per<strong>for</strong>mance <strong>pay</strong>. This type of policy works by strengthening therelationship between a teacher’s <strong>pay</strong> and abil<strong>it</strong>y. A second implication of the standard Roy modelis that increasing teacher salaries will unambiguously increase the average abil<strong>it</strong>y of <strong>teachers</strong>. <strong>The</strong>intu<strong>it</strong>ion is that by raising teacher <strong>pay</strong>, the profession will attract workers w<strong>it</strong>h higher levels ofabil<strong>it</strong>y <strong>for</strong> each level of worker credentials.This study is designed <strong>to</strong> test <strong>for</strong> evidence of an effect of teacher <strong>pay</strong> on the qual<strong>it</strong>y of educationprovided by a district through both avenues: efficiency and teacher qual<strong>it</strong>y. To do so, I test <strong>for</strong> arelationship between teacher <strong>pay</strong> and teacher turnover, the characteristics of new teacher hires,student achievement, and student dropout rates.1 In this model, the standard case is characterized by: var(ln(a)) > cov(ln(a), ln(c)) (Heckman & Honor 1990).6


3 Empirical Methods and DataI estimate several econometric models of the relationship between district-level outcomes andteacher salaries. <strong>The</strong> models I estimate are of the following general <strong>for</strong>m:y jt = β ′ x jt + θ j + α t + ɛ jt (1)y jt is the outcome of interest in district j during time t, which include district level teacher turnover,average student test scores at the district level, district measures of student dropout rates, and thecharacteristics of new teacher hires. <strong>The</strong> vec<strong>to</strong>r x jt includes district characteristics that vary overtime, including district j’s contract salary averaged across teacher experience and education levels.<strong>The</strong> parameters θ j and α t are a district fixed effect and year fixed effect respectively, and ɛ jt is anerror term that includes district-level unobservables that vary by year. β is a vec<strong>to</strong>r of parametersthat I intend <strong>to</strong> estimate, which are assumed <strong>to</strong> represent a linear approximation of the causalrelationship between the district’s time-varying characteristics and district-level outcomes. In thisstudy I am interested in estimating the parameter that represents the causal relationship betweenthe district’s salary schedule and district-level outcomes.To estimate the parameters in equation 1, I employ detailed district-level data from the OklahomaState Department of <strong>Education</strong> (OSDE) and the National Center <strong>for</strong> <strong>Education</strong> Statistics(NCES). <strong>The</strong> data from OSDE is a teacher-level long<strong>it</strong>udinal file containing measures of teacherexperience, education, <strong>pay</strong>, benef<strong>it</strong>s, subject taught, and district affiliation. <strong>The</strong> data contains thisin<strong>for</strong>mation <strong>for</strong> all public school <strong>teachers</strong> in the state over the years 2006-2012.From this data, I am able <strong>to</strong> observe or impute the entire teacher salary schedule <strong>for</strong> the state’s39 largest school districts <strong>for</strong> each year. <strong>The</strong> sample is lim<strong>it</strong>ed <strong>to</strong> large districts because theyallow one <strong>to</strong> observe several points on the salary schedule in each time period, making <strong>it</strong> possible<strong>to</strong> construct full salary schedules across all years. Appendix table 3 shows the districts that areincluded in the final sample. <strong>The</strong> 39 districts included in the sample employ 52 percent of theState’s <strong>teachers</strong> and service 54 percent of the state’s students.7


<strong>The</strong> data also provide the necessary in<strong>for</strong>mation <strong>to</strong> calculate the teacher turnover rate <strong>for</strong> eachdistrict <strong>for</strong> six of the seven time periods. I am able <strong>to</strong> merge this data w<strong>it</strong>h other annual district leveloutcome variables maintained by NCES and OSDE, which include average student achievement,dropout rates, and average teacher characteristics of new hires.I estimate the parameters equation 1 using the following methods: first-differencing (FD),fixed-effects (FE), and first differencing by two-stage least squares (FD 2SLS). <strong>The</strong> FE and FDmethods provide consistent estima<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>for</strong> β assuming that unobservables in ɛ jt are uncorrelatedw<strong>it</strong>h x jt , which includes teacher <strong>pay</strong>, in each time period. That is, these estima<strong>to</strong>rs will tend <strong>to</strong>be close <strong>to</strong> the true causal parameter in large samples as long as any time varying unobservablesat the district level are not correlated the district’s teacher salary schedule or any other observabletime-varying district level covariates.A common concern <strong>for</strong> bias in FE and FD estimates of equation 1, is the notion that teacher<strong>pay</strong> may be correlated w<strong>it</strong>h unobserved time-varying parental support at the district level. That is,districts that experience a growth in parental support will likely experience better student outcomesand will have an easier time obtaining funding <strong>for</strong> higher teacher salaries. Under this scenario, evenif teacher salaries have no causal effect on student achievement, FD and FE estimation of equation1 will attribute the better student outcomes <strong>to</strong> growth in teacher salaries. In this case, the estima<strong>to</strong>rswill be biased upward. In general any correlation between time varying unobservables ɛ jt and thedistrict’s salary schedule will cause bias in the FD and FE estima<strong>to</strong>rs.It can be argued that many, if not most, prior studies of the effect of teacher <strong>pay</strong> on studentachievement are contaminated by the bias described here. This study provides a contribution <strong>to</strong> thel<strong>it</strong>erature by estimating this causal relationship w<strong>it</strong>h a method that is potentially less susceptible <strong>to</strong>bias. To reduce the potential <strong>for</strong> bias in my estimates, I explo<strong>it</strong> changes Oklahoma’s state mandatedminimum salary schedule. State imposed variation in teacher salaries allow me <strong>to</strong> identify theeffects of changes in salaries that are independent of district level unobservables, hence avoidingthe classic om<strong>it</strong>ted variable bias described above. To explo<strong>it</strong> this exogenous variation in <strong>teachers</strong>alaries, I estimate equation 1 by combining a first-differencing and 2SLS procedure. In the first-8


differenced equation, I use the district’s mandated salary increase required <strong>to</strong> meet the minimumsalary schedule as an instrument <strong>for</strong> a district’s change in salary schedule. This method producesa consistent estima<strong>to</strong>r <strong>for</strong> the causal relationship between teacher salaries and student outcomesas long as the state’s minimum salary schedule is sufficiently correlated w<strong>it</strong>h teacher <strong>pay</strong> and thestate’s minimum salary schedule is uncorrelated w<strong>it</strong>h district-level time-varying unobservables thatinfluence student achievement and teacher outcomes.<strong>The</strong> Oklahoma state minimum teacher salary schedule was first established as part of HouseBill 1017 2 and first <strong>to</strong>ok effect during the 1991-92 school year. <strong>The</strong> state minimum salary schedulewas adjusted twice during the period <strong>for</strong> which data on teacher <strong>pay</strong> and student achievementare available. Between the 2005-06 and 2006-07 school years Oklahoma increased <strong>it</strong>s minimumteacher salary schedule by $3,000 <strong>for</strong> every teacher. In the following year, the schedule was againincreased, but this time the raises varied by teacher experience and degree. <strong>The</strong> 2007-08 minimumsalary schedule included a raise of $600 <strong>for</strong> all <strong>teachers</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h under 10 years of experience. For<strong>teachers</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h 10 or <strong>more</strong> years of experience the raises in the minimum salary schedule dependedon education: $1,025 <strong>for</strong> teacher w<strong>it</strong>h a Bachelor’s degree; $1,450 <strong>for</strong> <strong>teachers</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h a Master’s degree;$2,300 <strong>for</strong> <strong>teachers</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h a Doc<strong>to</strong>ral degree. Oklahoma has not changed the minimum salaryschedule since 2008.Figure 1 illustrates the average (across years of experience) state minimum salary schedule <strong>for</strong><strong>teachers</strong> who have a Bachelor’s degree and varying years of experience over the time period 2005-06 through 2011-12. Notice the large increase in the minimum salary schedule in 2006-07 <strong>for</strong> allexperience levels and the smaller increase in the salary schedule in 2007-08.A key requirement <strong>for</strong> the 2SLS estimation is that the state minimum salary schedule musthave an influence on <strong>teachers</strong>’ actual salaries. In other words, the minimum salary schedule mustbe binding <strong>for</strong> some districts. Figure 2 provides illustrative evidence that this is indeed the case.Figure 2 shows the mean contract salary paid <strong>to</strong> <strong>teachers</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h a Bachelor’s degree and 0-9 yearsof experience <strong>for</strong> each of the 39 districts in the sample. For each district, the changes in the state2 Laws 1989, 1st Ex. Session, c.29


Figure 1: State Minimum Salary Schedule by YearSalary in thousands30 35 402006 2008 2010 2012Yearmin BA salary 0-4yrsmin BA salary 10-14yrsmin BA salary 5-9yrsmin BA salary 15-25yrsFigure 2: District Average Contract Salaries <strong>for</strong> BA 0-9yrs by YearSalary in thousands30 32 34 36 382006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012Yearnumber of districts = 3910


minimum salary schedule are closely matched by changes in the districts’ salary schedules.Figure 2 also identifies a potential weakness of the data. In order <strong>to</strong> separate the effect of achange in the district salary from a year effect, there must be sufficient variation in the timing ofdistrict salary changes. Ideally, w<strong>it</strong>hin each year there would be a group of districts that changedtheir salary schedule (a treatment group) and a group of district that did not alter their salaryschedule (a control group). This type of variation would allow one <strong>to</strong> clearly separate the effec<strong>to</strong>f a change in wage on the outcome variable from a year effect. As the figure illustrates, and aslater results show, there is not significant variation in the timing of salary changes across districts,which makes the separate identification of year fixed-effects and salary effects difficult.4 Results4.1 Turnover analysisI begin the analysis by probing <strong>for</strong> an indirect link between teacher <strong>pay</strong> and education qual<strong>it</strong>yby examining the relationship between salaries and teacher turnover. Figure 3 illustrates changesin the median teacher turnover rate and median teacher <strong>pay</strong> <strong>for</strong> the largest 39 districts in Oklahomaover the years 2006-2012. Although the data provides a lim<strong>it</strong>ed view of the long-term trends, thereappears <strong>to</strong> be a negative relationship between teacher turnover and teacher salaries. For example,from 2006 <strong>to</strong> 2010 median teacher salaries increased by about 10 percent, and at the same timeover this period the median turnover rate decreased by 5 percentage points, which is nearly a 40percent decline in the median turnover rate.To <strong>for</strong>mally test <strong>for</strong> a relationship between teacher <strong>pay</strong> and turnover, tables 1 and 2 presentfirst-difference (FD), fixed-effects (FE), and first-difference by two-stage least squares (FD 2SLS)estimates of equation 1. For each table, I estimate equation 1 using a measure of voluntary teacherturnover as the dependent variable, which is defined as follows:V olT urn jt = #leavers jt − #cut jt#<strong>teachers</strong> jt(2)11


Figure 3: Median Salaries and Median Turnover by YearSalary in thousands30 31 32 33 34 358 10 12 14% Teacher Turnover2006 2008 2010 2012YearMedian BA salary 0-9yrsMedian Voluntary Turnover %Min Salary Sched. BA 0-9yrswhere V olT urn jt is voluntary turnover in district j at time t, #leavers jt is the number of <strong>teachers</strong>who were in district j during time t but were not employed in district j during time t + 1,#<strong>teachers</strong> jt is the number of <strong>teachers</strong> in district j during time t, and #cut jt is the number ofteaching pos<strong>it</strong>ions cut: #<strong>teachers</strong> jt -#<strong>teachers</strong> j,t+1 if the difference is greater than or equal <strong>to</strong>zero.In all specifications I control <strong>for</strong> county level economic cond<strong>it</strong>ions w<strong>it</strong>h measures of the averageearnings of workers in the service sec<strong>to</strong>r and unemployment rates. In add<strong>it</strong>ion <strong>to</strong> these controlvariables, the tables show estimates of three separate specifications, which are reported by column.In columns 1 and 4 of table 1 and column 1 of table 2, I report estimates of equation 1 by controlling<strong>for</strong> district fixed-effects and assuming year fixed-effects are zero. In columns 2 and 5 of table 1and column 2 of table 2, I control <strong>for</strong> state-level effects by adding a time trend. In columns 3 and6 of table 1 and column 3 of table 2, I drop the time trend and control <strong>for</strong> state-level effects w<strong>it</strong>hyear fixed-effects.In both tables the key explana<strong>to</strong>ry variable used <strong>to</strong> measure the district’s salary schedule is thedistrict’s mean contract salary <strong>for</strong> <strong>teachers</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h a Bachelor’s degree and 0-9 years of experience.12


<strong>The</strong> average salary was calculated using the district’s contract salary, not observed teacher salaries.For example, this was constructed by averaging the contract salaries <strong>for</strong> each of the following10 cells on the district’s salary schedule: BA and 0 years experience through BA and 9 years ofexperience. In both tables I estimate the effect of teacher salaries on the next period’s voluntaryteacher turnover (the effect of teacher salary in period t on turnover in period t + 1). In table1, columns 1-3 differ from columns 4-6 in estimation method. I report FD estimation results incolumns 1-3 and FE results in columns 4-6.Table 1: First Differencing and Fixed EffectsDependent Var: (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)Voluntary Turnover t+1 FD FD FD FE FE FEBA salary 0-9yrs/1,000 -0.973*** -1.108*** -0.405 -0.960*** -1.071*** -0.454*(0.264) (0.298) (0.363) (0.263) (0.286) (0.256)Avg Earn in County/1,000 1.085*** 0.562 0.249 0.711** 0.551 0.307(0.286) (0.529) (0.348) (0.320) (0.451) (0.330)County Unemp. Rate -1.134*** -1.470*** -0.885 -0.745*** -0.943*** -0.057(0.194) (0.322) (0.593) (0.171) (0.291) (0.580)Observations 156 156 156 195 195 195R 2 0.188 0.204 0.357 0.205 0.208 0.353District FEs Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesTime Trend No Yes No No Yes NoYear FEs No No Yes No No YesNumber of Districts 39 39 39 39 39 39standard errors in parenthesesstandard errors are robust <strong>to</strong> arb<strong>it</strong>rary heteroskedastic<strong>it</strong>y and correlation w<strong>it</strong>hin districtdependent variable is percent voluntary turnover in t+1*** p


is zero (i.e. the minimum salary schedule was non-binding).Appendix table 4 shows first stage results <strong>for</strong> the 2SLS estimates in table 2. Notice the instrumentis strongly related <strong>to</strong> district salary when controlling <strong>for</strong> county economic cond<strong>it</strong>ions anddistrict fixed effects and a time trend, but not significant when controlling <strong>for</strong> year fixed-effects. Asa result, the FD 2SLS estimate in column 3 of table 2 should be disregarded since the instrumentalvariable is invalid in that specification.Table 2: First Differencing by 2SLSDependent Var: (1) (2) (3)Voluntary Turnover t+1 FD 2SLS FD 2SLS FD 2SLSBA salary 0-9yrs/1,000 -1.287*** -1.424*** -12.258(0.332) (0.370) (12.044)Avg Earnings in County/1,000 1.367*** 0.729 0.997(0.314) (0.471) (1.485)County Unemp. Rate -1.170*** -1.565*** -0.790(0.196) (0.323) (1.372)Observations 156 156 156District FEs Yes Yes YesTime Trend No Yes NoYear FEs No No Yesstandard errors in parenthesesstandard errors are robust <strong>to</strong> arb<strong>it</strong>rary heteroskedastic<strong>it</strong>y and correlation w<strong>it</strong>hin districtdependent variable is percent voluntary turnover in t+1district’s mandated salary increase <strong>for</strong> min salary compliance used as instrument*** p


this complication, the FE model still suggests a negative and statistically significant relationshipbetween teacher salary and turnover.<strong>The</strong> models also indicate other effects that are consistent w<strong>it</strong>h economic theory. In add<strong>it</strong>ion<strong>to</strong> the effects of teacher salaries on teacher turnover, the results suggests a pos<strong>it</strong>ive relationshipbetween county-level earnings and teacher turnover. That is, as salaries in other occupations riserelative <strong>to</strong> teacher salaries, teacher turnover increases. Also, the models suggest a negative relationshipbetween county-level unemployment rates and teacher turnover. That is, as the probabil<strong>it</strong>yof finding employment outside of teaching falls, fewer <strong>teachers</strong> will leave their current teachingpos<strong>it</strong>ion. Both of these effects are consistent w<strong>it</strong>h what one would expect if <strong>teachers</strong> are responsive<strong>to</strong> alternative employment opportun<strong>it</strong>ies.<strong>The</strong> size of the estimated effects in these models is fairly substantial. For example, as a conservativecalculation, if one accepts the smallest of the estimated effects presented above (-0.5) asthe true causal effect of teacher salary on turnover, then that suggests a $2,000 increase in <strong>teachers</strong>alary will reduce a district’s voluntary turnover rate by one percentage point. While that soundssmall, in Oklahoma the average district voluntary turnover rate in 2011 was 12 percent, or 12 ou<strong>to</strong>f 100 <strong>teachers</strong> turnover each year. <strong>The</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e a $2,000 increase in teacher <strong>pay</strong> would reduce this <strong>to</strong>11 percent, which is an 8 percent reduction in the turnover rate. <strong>The</strong> higher end estimates suggestthat a $2,000 increase in teacher <strong>pay</strong> would reduce teacher turnover by as much as 2 percentagepoints, which is roughly a 17 percent reduction in the turnover rate.4.2 Characteristics of new teacher hiresanalysis <strong>for</strong>thcoming4.3 Student test scoresanalysis <strong>for</strong>thcoming15


4.4 Dropout ratesanalysis <strong>for</strong>thcoming5 Implications<strong>for</strong>thcomingReferencesAkerlof, George A. 1982. “Labor Contracts as Partial Gift Exchange.” <strong>The</strong> Quarterly Journal ofEconomics, 97(4): 543–569.Clotfelter, Charles, Elizabeth Glennie, Helen Ladd, and Jacob Vigdor. 2008. “Would HigherSalaries Keep Teachers In High-poverty Schools? Evidence from a Policy Intervention inNorth Carolina.” Journal of Public Economics, 92(56): 1352–1370.Hanushek, Eric A., and Steven G. Rivkin. 2010. “Generalizations about Using Value-AddedMeasures of Teacher Qual<strong>it</strong>y.” American Economic Review, 100(2): 267–271.Hanushek, Eric A., John F. Kain, and Steven G. Rivkin. 2004. “Why Public Schools LoseTeachers.” <strong>The</strong> Journal of Human Resources, 39(2): pp. 326–354.Hanushek, Eric A., John F. Kain, Daniel M. O’Brien, and Steven G. Rivkin. 2005. “<strong>The</strong>Market <strong>for</strong> Teacher Qual<strong>it</strong>y.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 11154.Hanushek, Eric A., Steven G. Rivkin, Richard Rothstein, and Michael Podgursky. 2004.“How <strong>to</strong> Improve the Supply of High-Qual<strong>it</strong>y Teachers.” Brookings Papers on <strong>Education</strong>Policy, , (7): 7–44.Heckman, James J., and Bo E. Honor. 1990. “<strong>The</strong> Empirical Content of the Roy Model.” Econometrica,58(5): pp. 1121–1149.Jacob, Brian A., and Lars Lefgren. 2008. “Can Principals Identify Effective Teachers? Evidenceon Subjective Per<strong>for</strong>mance Evaluation in <strong>Education</strong>.” Journal of Labor Economics,26(1): 101–136.Kane, Thomas J., and Douglas O. Staiger. 2008. “Estimating Teacher Impacts on StudentAchievement: An Experimental Evaluation.” National Bureau of Economic Research WorkingPaper 14607.Kane, Thomas J., Jonah E. Rockoff, and Douglas O. Staiger. 2008. “What <strong>Does</strong> CertificationTell Us About Teacher Effectiveness? Evidence from New York C<strong>it</strong>y.” Economics of <strong>Education</strong>Review, 27(6): 615–631.16


Loeb, Susanna, and Marianne E. Page. 2000. “Examining the Link between Teacher Wages andStudent Outcomes: <strong>The</strong> Importance of Alternative Labor Market Opportun<strong>it</strong>ies and Non-Pecuniary Variation.” <strong>The</strong> Review of Economics and Statistics, 82(3): 393–408.Rockoff, Jonah E. 2004. “<strong>The</strong> Impact of Individual Teachers on Student Achievement: Evidencefrom Panel Data.” <strong>The</strong> American Economic Review, 94(2): 247–252.Ronfeldt, Matthew, Hamil<strong>to</strong>n Lank<strong>for</strong>d, Susanna Loeb, and James Wyckoff. 2011. “HowTeacher Turnover Harms Student Achievement.” National Bureau of Economic ResearchWorking Paper 17176.Rothstein, Jesse. 2010. “Teacher Qual<strong>it</strong>y in <strong>Education</strong>al Production: Tracking, Decay, and StudentAchievement.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(1): 175–214.Roy, A. D. 1951. “Some Thoughts on the Distribution of Earnings.” Ox<strong>for</strong>d Economic Papers,3(2): pp. 135–146.Shapiro, Carl, and Joseph E. Stigl<strong>it</strong>z. 1984. “Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker DisciplineDevice.” <strong>The</strong> American Economic Review, 74(3): 433–444.Snyder, T. D., and S. A. Dillow. 2011. Digest of <strong>Education</strong> Statistics 2010 (NCES 2011-015).National Center <strong>for</strong> <strong>Education</strong> Statistics, Inst<strong>it</strong>ute of <strong>Education</strong> Sciences, U.S. Department ofEduca<strong>to</strong>n. Washing<strong>to</strong>n, DC.Staiger, Douglas O., and Jonah E. Rockoff. 2010. “Searching <strong>for</strong> Effective Teachers w<strong>it</strong>h ImperfectIn<strong>for</strong>mation.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24(3): 97–118.AAppendix17


Table 3: Districts in Sample: Characteristics in 2009-10District Students FTE TeachersALTUS 4,001 280.5ARDMORE 3,081 205.8BARTLESVILLE 5,971 400.5BIXBY 4,784 267.8BROKEN ARROW 16,618 952.5CLAREMORE 4,168 270COWETA 3,263 194DEER CREEK 3,577 229.9EDMOND 20,750 1,174.80EL RENO 2,453 163.8ENID 6,896 450.7GROVE 2,561 163.1GUTHRIE 3,309 216.4GUYMON 2,726 167.1HARRAH 2,235 153.1JENKS 10,162 577.6LAWTON 16,398 1,117.80MIDWEST CITY-DEL CITY 14,643 947.5MOORE 21,675 1,285.50MUSKOGEE 6,567 383.4MUSTANG 8,607 503.8NORMAN 14,363 943.2OKLAHOMA CITY 42,549 2,589.60OWASSO 9,034 497.9PONCA CITY 5,157 330.2PUTNAM CITY 18,700 1,199.60SAND SPRINGS 5,412 327.3SAPULPA 4,149 253.6SHAWNEE 4,120 262.3SKIATOOK 2,546 144.2STILLWATER 5,650 360TAHLEQUAH 3,555 243.7TECUMSEH 2,299 155TULSA 41,493 2,739.00UNION 15,010 865.7WAGONER 2,475 179.1WESTERN HEIGHTS 3,534 254.4WOODWARD 2,684 161.5YUKON 7,209 414.839 District Total 354,384 22,027STATE TOTAL 654,802 42,614Percent of State Total 54% 52%18


Table 4: 2SLS First Stage ResultsDependent Var: (1) (2) (3)change in BA salary 0-9yrs OLS OLS OLSState Mandated Salary Increase 1.268*** 1.221*** 0.091(0.135) (0.118) (0.078)Observations 156 156 156R 2 0.754 0.766 0.917District FEs Yes Yes YesTime Trend No Yes NoYear FEs No No Yescluster-robust standard errors in parentheses*** p

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!