12.07.2015 Views

Indigenous Peoples, Poverty, and Self-Determination in Australia ...

Indigenous Peoples, Poverty, and Self-Determination in Australia ...

Indigenous Peoples, Poverty, and Self-Determination in Australia ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Jo<strong>in</strong>t Occasional Papers on on Native Affairs<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong><strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Australia</strong>,New Zeal<strong>and</strong>, Canada <strong>and</strong>the United Statesby Stephen CornellNative Nations Institutefor Leadership, Management,<strong>and</strong> PolicyJOPNA No. 2006-02The Harvard Projecton American IndianEconomic Development


ABOUT THE NATIVE NATIONS INSTITUTEThe Native Nations Institute for Leadership, Management, <strong>and</strong> Policy (NNI)is part of the Udall Center for Studies <strong>in</strong> Public Policy, a research <strong>and</strong> outreachunit of the University of Arizona. Founded <strong>in</strong> 2001 by the university <strong>and</strong> theMorris K. Udall Foundation, NNI provides research, policy analysis, <strong>and</strong> executiveeducation services to Native nations <strong>and</strong> other <strong>in</strong>digenous organizations <strong>in</strong>the United States, Canada, <strong>and</strong> elsewhere. Much of NNI’s work builds on <strong>and</strong>cont<strong>in</strong>ues research orig<strong>in</strong>ally carried out by the Harvard Project on AmericanIndian Economic Development at Harvard University. The two organizationsshare some staff <strong>and</strong> work closely together <strong>in</strong> a variety of research <strong>and</strong> educationalactivities.NATIVE NATIONS INSTITUTEFOR LEADERSHIP, MANAGEMENT, AND POLICYUdall Center for Studies <strong>in</strong> Public PolicyThe University of Arizona803 East First Street, Tucson, AZ 85719Tel 520 626-0664 Fax 520 626-3664http://nni.arizona.eduABOUT THE HARVARD PROJECT ONAMERICAN INDIAN ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTFounded <strong>in</strong> 1987, the Harvard Project on American Indian Economic Development(Harvard Project) is housed with<strong>in</strong> the Malcolm Wiener Center forSocial Policy at the John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University.Through applied research <strong>and</strong> service, the Harvard Project aims to underst<strong>and</strong><strong>and</strong> foster the conditions under which susta<strong>in</strong>ed, self-determ<strong>in</strong>ed social<strong>and</strong> economic development is achieved among American Indian nations. TheHarvard Project’s core activities <strong>in</strong>clude research, advisory services, executiveeducation <strong>and</strong> the adm<strong>in</strong>istration of a tribal governance awards program. In allof its activities, the Harvard Project collaborates with the Native Nations Institutefor Leadership, Management <strong>and</strong> Policy at the University of Arizona.HARVARD PROJECT ON AMERICANINDIAN ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTJohn F. Kennedy School of GovernmentHarvard University79 John F. Kennedy Street, Cambridge, MA 02138Tel 617 495-1480 Fax 617 496-3900http://www.ksg.harvard.edu/hpaied


Cornell<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong><strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Australia</strong>,New Zeal<strong>and</strong>, Canada <strong>and</strong>the United StatesStephen CornellJOPNA No. 2006-02


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>About the AuthorStephen Cornell is Professor of Sociology <strong>and</strong> of Public Adm<strong>in</strong>istration <strong>and</strong>Policy <strong>and</strong> Director of the Udall Center for Studies <strong>in</strong> Public Policy at TheUniversity of Arizona, where he also is a Faculty Associate of the university’sNative Nations Institute for Leadership, Management, <strong>and</strong> Policy. He cofounded<strong>and</strong> today co-directs the Harvard Project on American IndianEconomic Development. His Ph.D. is from the University of Chicago. Hetaught at Harvard University <strong>and</strong> the University of California, San Diego, beforejo<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the Arizona faculty <strong>in</strong> 1998.AcknowledgementsThis paper orig<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> conversations with Miriam Jorgensen, <strong>and</strong> hercontribution to it has been substantial; also significant have been cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>gconversations <strong>and</strong> collaboration with Joseph P. Kalt. I am grateful to DianeSmith for her suggestions <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>sights, to Kimberly Abraham <strong>and</strong> Ian Recordfor research assistance, <strong>and</strong> to the editors for their helpful commentary.Photography creditsClockwise from top: 1. Yup’ik women gather<strong>in</strong>g basket materials at Tununak,Alaska, photo courtesy of the National Museum of the American Indian,Smithsonian Institution; 2. Choctaw Health Center, Mississippi B<strong>and</strong> ofChoctaw Indians, photo courtesy of the Harvard Project; 3. Apprentice,New Zeal<strong>and</strong> Maori Arts <strong>and</strong> Crafts Institute, Rotorua, New Zeal<strong>and</strong>,photo by Ian Record, NNI.


Cornell<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong><strong>in</strong> <strong>Australia</strong>, New Zeal<strong>and</strong>, Canada <strong>and</strong> the United StatesStephen CornellJOPNA No. 2006-02ISBN 10: 1-931143-33-1ISBN 13: 978-1-931143-33-2Library of Congress Control Number: 2006940162© 2006 by the Native Nations Institute for Leadership,Management,<strong>and</strong> Policyon behalf of the Arizona Board of Regents<strong>and</strong> theHarvard Project on American Indian Economic DevelopmentRepr<strong>in</strong>ted with permission from<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong>: An International PerspectiveEdited by Robyn Eversole, John-Andrew McNeish, <strong>and</strong> Alberto D. CimadamoreZed Books <strong>in</strong> association with CROP International Studies<strong>in</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong> Research, 2005


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>


Cornell<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong><strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Australia</strong>,New Zeal<strong>and</strong>, Canada <strong>and</strong>the United StatesStephen Cornell<strong>Australia</strong>, New Zeal<strong>and</strong>, Canada <strong>and</strong> the United States are amongthe world’s wealthiest nations. It is an often noted irony—<strong>and</strong> anoccasional source of embarrassment to the governments of thesecountries—that the <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples with<strong>in</strong> their borders are<strong>in</strong> each case among their poorest citizens. The irony is eitherexpla<strong>in</strong>ed away or made all the greater, depend<strong>in</strong>g on your frameof m<strong>in</strong>d, by the fact that the wealth of these countries has beenbuilt substantially on resources taken from these peoples, whosepoverty—<strong>in</strong> the gr<strong>and</strong> scheme of th<strong>in</strong>gs—is a recent creation.Although my <strong>in</strong>terest is not <strong>in</strong> the sources of <strong>Indigenous</strong> povertybut <strong>in</strong> how to overcome it, this poverty is the subject of this paper.In what follows, I consider the comparability of <strong>Indigenous</strong>peoples’ situations <strong>in</strong> these countries, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the mismatch <strong>in</strong>all four cases between <strong>Indigenous</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>s for self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation<strong>and</strong> state programs to address socio-economic disadvantage. Ithen summarize evidence from the United States that <strong>Indigenous</strong>self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>and</strong> self-government are essential bases forimprov<strong>in</strong>g the socio-economic conditions of <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples,. For example, accord<strong>in</strong>g to the United Nations Development Progamme’s2002 World Development Report, <strong>in</strong> 2000 Canada ranked third among countriesof the world, <strong>Australia</strong> fifth, the U.S. sixth, <strong>and</strong> New Zeal<strong>and</strong> n<strong>in</strong>eteenthon the Human Development Index, which comb<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong>dicators of knowledge,<strong>in</strong>dividual longevity <strong>and</strong> the st<strong>and</strong>ard of liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> each country (United NationsDevelopment Programme 2003).


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>explore some of the issues raised by this evidence, <strong>and</strong> concludewith implications for policy-makers.One might ask whether U.S. evidence on <strong>Indigenous</strong> poverty isrelevant to the three other countries listed above. There is as yet littlesystematic research that addresses the po<strong>in</strong>t, <strong>and</strong> this paper drawsmost directly on work carried out with American Indian nations<strong>in</strong> the United States. My colleagues <strong>and</strong> I have done additional,but less comprehensive, research with First Nations <strong>in</strong> Canada<strong>and</strong> have had only prelim<strong>in</strong>ary discussions about governance <strong>and</strong>development issues with Maori <strong>and</strong> Aborig<strong>in</strong>al peoples <strong>in</strong> NewZeal<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Australia</strong>. Consequently, the conclusions I drawfrom non-U.S. research are necessarily speculative. Nevertheless,they are worth explor<strong>in</strong>g. In all four countries, <strong>Indigenous</strong> povertyhas been not only deep <strong>and</strong> widespread but persistent, defy<strong>in</strong>gpolicy prescriptions. Both <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples <strong>and</strong> the states thatseek to address this problem face daunt<strong>in</strong>g challenges. Whatworks <strong>in</strong> one country may hold lessons for others. At the veryleast, it may po<strong>in</strong>t research <strong>in</strong> productive directions.DifferencesDo the historical <strong>and</strong> cultural differences among these fourcountries <strong>and</strong> their <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples overwhelm the <strong>in</strong>sightswe might draw from any one of them? What grounds have we forth<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g that what works <strong>in</strong> one might be relevant to the others?. “Colleagues” <strong>in</strong> this context refers to the community of scholars, practitioners<strong>and</strong> students concerned with <strong>in</strong>digenous governance <strong>and</strong> developmentissues <strong>and</strong> affiliated with the Native Nations Institute at The University ofArizona <strong>and</strong> the Harvard Project on American Indian Economic Developmentat Harvard University.. Although some of us have served as advisors on research efforts <strong>in</strong> bothcountries.


CornellObviously the differences are substantial, both historically <strong>and</strong>today. For example, Brita<strong>in</strong> recognized Maori sovereignty over theNorth Isl<strong>and</strong> of New Zeal<strong>and</strong> early on <strong>and</strong> then, over the years, setout to ext<strong>in</strong>guish it. In contrast, it gave no recognition to Aborig<strong>in</strong>alsovereignty—or even occupancy—<strong>in</strong> <strong>Australia</strong>. Warfare between<strong>Indigenous</strong> groups <strong>and</strong> European settlers <strong>and</strong> states was frequent<strong>and</strong> at times prolonged <strong>in</strong> the United States <strong>and</strong> New Zeal<strong>and</strong>, butmuch less common <strong>in</strong> Canada <strong>and</strong> <strong>Australia</strong>. Serial treaty-mak<strong>in</strong>gtook place <strong>in</strong> Canada <strong>and</strong> the United States, but was unknown <strong>in</strong><strong>Australia</strong>, while treaty-mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> New Zeal<strong>and</strong> was limited tothe Treaty of Waitangi <strong>in</strong> 1840—itself quite a different enterprisefrom Canadian <strong>and</strong> U.S. treaty-mak<strong>in</strong>g (Pocock 2000)—which,despite the refusal of some Maori to sign it, was viewed by theCrown as establish<strong>in</strong>g British sovereignty over the whole of theNorth Isl<strong>and</strong>.Likewise, once European control had been established, theadm<strong>in</strong>istration of <strong>Indigenous</strong> affairs differed <strong>in</strong> numerous waysamong these countries. In the United States, for example, relationswith Indian nations have been under the exclusive control of thefederal government, with <strong>in</strong>dividual states play<strong>in</strong>g only a m<strong>in</strong>orrole. In Canada, on the other h<strong>and</strong>, despite the prom<strong>in</strong>ence of thefederal government, the role of the prov<strong>in</strong>ces <strong>in</strong> relations with FirstNations has been substantial, especially <strong>in</strong> recent years (Morse1998). In <strong>Australia</strong>, the adm<strong>in</strong>istration of Aborig<strong>in</strong>al affairslargely ignored “tribal” boundaries <strong>and</strong> often fostered a mix<strong>in</strong>gof peoples, while such boundaries eventually became the basis ofthe organization of relations with American Indians, <strong>and</strong> bothtreaty-mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> the adm<strong>in</strong>istration of Indian affairs <strong>in</strong> manycases rigidified group boundaries or <strong>in</strong>troduced new ones. Wecould po<strong>in</strong>t to numerous other legal, political <strong>and</strong> organizationaldifferences <strong>in</strong> the history of <strong>Indigenous</strong>-settler relations <strong>in</strong> thesefour countries.Today, numerous differences rema<strong>in</strong>, from the details of<strong>Indigenous</strong> relations with central governments to l<strong>and</strong> rights,from demographics to socio-economic conditions. Neitherthe relative size of the <strong>Indigenous</strong> l<strong>and</strong> bases nor the officially


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>recognized rights of <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples to l<strong>and</strong> are the same <strong>in</strong>all four countries. Recognition of Native title <strong>and</strong> restorationof some l<strong>and</strong> rights to Aborig<strong>in</strong>al <strong>Australia</strong>ns are very recent,while most American Indian nations have exercised at least somejurisdiction over reserved l<strong>and</strong>s for decades <strong>and</strong>, <strong>in</strong> some cases,much longer, <strong>and</strong> some of those reserved l<strong>and</strong>s are extensive.Many First Nations <strong>in</strong> Canada have some measure of control overreserved l<strong>and</strong>s, but <strong>in</strong> nearly all such cases the l<strong>and</strong>s are m<strong>in</strong>iscule<strong>in</strong> extent, while Maori, hav<strong>in</strong>g suffered massive l<strong>and</strong> losses overthe years, have been engaged <strong>in</strong> a major effort <strong>in</strong> recent decades torega<strong>in</strong> significant l<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> resources.In all four countries the <strong>Indigenous</strong> populations are small, butnot equally so. At the turn of the twentieth century, <strong>Indigenous</strong>peoples made up approximately 1.5 percent of the overall U.S.population, just over 2 percent of that of <strong>Australia</strong>, more than 4percent of that of Canada, but close to 15 percent of the populationof New Zeal<strong>and</strong>. Tribal or equivalent groups range widely <strong>in</strong> sizefrom populations of under one hundred, found <strong>in</strong> each country,to the Navajo Nation <strong>in</strong> the United States, more than a quarterof a million strong. More than half of the Indian population <strong>in</strong>the United States live <strong>in</strong> urban areas; an even higher percentageof Maori do. While many Aborig<strong>in</strong>al <strong>Australia</strong>ns likewise live <strong>in</strong>cities <strong>and</strong> towns, they are much more likely than American Indiansor Maori to live <strong>in</strong> remote regions. <strong>Indigenous</strong> groups are amongthe poorest populations <strong>in</strong> each country, but there are significantdifferences <strong>in</strong> social <strong>and</strong> economic conditions. In <strong>Australia</strong>, forexample, Aborig<strong>in</strong>al life expectancy at birth <strong>in</strong> 1991 was 59.6years but was 70.5 years for New Zeal<strong>and</strong> Maori <strong>and</strong> registeredIndians <strong>in</strong> Canada <strong>and</strong> 73.5 years for American Indians <strong>and</strong>Alaska Natives <strong>in</strong> the United States (Beavon <strong>and</strong> Cooke 2001). . The figure for the U.S. is from ; for <strong>Australia</strong>, from ; for Canada, from ; forNew Zeal<strong>and</strong>, from . All wereaccessed <strong>in</strong> March 2003.. For additional <strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>in</strong>digenous poverty <strong>in</strong> these four countries,


CornellCommonalitiesAlthough there are clear differences there are, however, alsosubstantial similarities among these four locations <strong>and</strong> thesituations of their <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples. The follow<strong>in</strong>g seemparticularly important <strong>and</strong> grounds for comparative <strong>in</strong>quiry.• All four are settler societies, states <strong>in</strong> which “the predom<strong>in</strong>antpopulation arises from immigrants <strong>and</strong> the <strong>Indigenous</strong>population has become a displaced m<strong>in</strong>ority” (Perry 1996:167).• All four contemporary societies are of predom<strong>in</strong>antly Britishheritage. Not only did immigrants from Great Brita<strong>in</strong> longdom<strong>in</strong>ate settler populations, but all four legal <strong>and</strong> politicalstructures draw heavily on English political traditions <strong>and</strong>common law. All are predom<strong>in</strong>antly English-speak<strong>in</strong>gsocieties today.• Furthermore, as Moran (2002: 1015-16) po<strong>in</strong>ts out, “countrieslike the United States, Canada, New Zeal<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Australia</strong>,despite important differences, are all structured by the factthat they are predom<strong>in</strong>antly English-speak<strong>in</strong>g settler cultureswhich have to a large extent supplanted <strong>in</strong>digenous peoples.”• But this fact structures not only these countries; it profoundlystructures the experience of their <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples as well.In all four, supplant<strong>in</strong>g these peoples has entailed enormous<strong>Indigenous</strong> resource losses, the eventual destruction of<strong>Indigenous</strong> economies <strong>and</strong> a good deal of social organization,precipitous population decl<strong>in</strong>es, <strong>and</strong> subjection to tutelary<strong>and</strong> assimilationist policies antagonistic to <strong>Indigenous</strong>cultures (for a summary of the record <strong>in</strong> three of the four, seeArmitage 1995).see Hunter (1999), Royal Commission on Aborig<strong>in</strong>al <strong>Peoples</strong> (1996), Durie(1998: ch. 4), Henson et al. (forthcom<strong>in</strong>g).


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>• In all four cases, this history had catastrophic <strong>and</strong> longlast<strong>in</strong>geffects on the orig<strong>in</strong>al <strong>in</strong>habitants. As noted above,<strong>Indigenous</strong> populations <strong>in</strong> each of these societies are at ornear the bottom of the scale of socio-economic welfare.• Despite this record, the disruptions <strong>and</strong> displacements thathave occurred <strong>in</strong> each of these societies have not resulted <strong>in</strong>the complete disappearance of <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples, eitherthrough warfare <strong>and</strong> disease or through assimilation. Ineach case, <strong>Indigenous</strong> populations survive, many of themnot simply as aggregations of <strong>in</strong>dividuals but as dist<strong>in</strong>ctcommunities concentrated on remnant l<strong>and</strong>s that have beenthe keys to their survival <strong>and</strong> over which they exercise vary<strong>in</strong>glevels of control.• Furthermore, <strong>in</strong> all four cases <strong>Indigenous</strong> populations—eitheras <strong>in</strong>dividuals or as communities—have long occupied legalpositions that differ <strong>in</strong> critical ways from those of ma<strong>in</strong>streampopulations. These positions vary from country to country<strong>and</strong> have changed over time, but <strong>Indigenous</strong> legal dist<strong>in</strong>ctionvis-à-vis the ma<strong>in</strong>stream has been a prom<strong>in</strong>ent feature ofeach country’s history. Among the issues debated <strong>in</strong> all fourcountries <strong>and</strong> not entirely resolved <strong>in</strong> any has been that ofthe rights of <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples to govern themselves <strong>in</strong> theirown ways <strong>and</strong> to shape their relations with encompass<strong>in</strong>gsocieties <strong>in</strong> ways of their own choos<strong>in</strong>g—<strong>in</strong> short, rightsto self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation. These rights have been variouslychallenged, ignored, underm<strong>in</strong>ed, acknowledged or modestlysupported over the years <strong>and</strong> across these cases, but as thetwenty-first century gets under way, they rema<strong>in</strong> at the veryheart of <strong>Indigenous</strong> concerns <strong>and</strong> of <strong>in</strong>ter-group tensions <strong>in</strong>each case.These commonalities suggest that comparative <strong>in</strong>quiry acrossthese four countries is by no means misplaced. On the contrary,the mix of convergence <strong>and</strong> variance <strong>in</strong>vites comparison: Why havethe patterns of <strong>in</strong>ter-group relations <strong>and</strong> of <strong>Indigenous</strong> political<strong>and</strong> economic development varied <strong>in</strong> the ways they have?


CornellThe present <strong>in</strong>quiry, while prompted <strong>in</strong> part by thesecommonalities, beg<strong>in</strong>s with a further pattern shared across thesecountries, but not <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the above list: the gap between<strong>Indigenous</strong> political assertions <strong>and</strong> the responses of states.<strong>Indigenous</strong> assertion <strong>and</strong> state responseRecently a senior official of the Canadian government remarked,<strong>in</strong> a private conversation, that the government of Canada wasquite will<strong>in</strong>g to address issues of equality <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Indigenous</strong>peoples, but was fundamentally unwill<strong>in</strong>g to address issues ofdifference. This was hardly the first time such reluctance hadsurfaced <strong>in</strong> Canada. In 1969, <strong>in</strong> a famous “White Paper,” thegovernment of Pierre Elliot Trudeau, <strong>in</strong> support of the idea that“we are all Canadians” (Perry 1996: 150), sought to end anydist<strong>in</strong>ct political or legal status for Canada’s Aborig<strong>in</strong>al peoples.Under the government plan, these peoples would differ from otherCanadians, as Armitage (1995: 80) says, “only <strong>in</strong> ethnic orig<strong>in</strong>, not<strong>in</strong> law.” Nor was the Canadian government alone. Other centralgovernments <strong>in</strong> these societies have also been reluctant to directlyaddress certa<strong>in</strong> <strong>Indigenous</strong> agendas.What are those agendas? They are diverse, of course, but <strong>in</strong> recentdecades <strong>Indigenous</strong> groups <strong>in</strong> all four countries have been engaged<strong>in</strong> both tribal <strong>and</strong> supra-tribal political work on behalf of selfdeterm<strong>in</strong>ation<strong>and</strong> self-governance. The core of their argument isabout rights. From a Western perspective, the argument is rooted<strong>in</strong> an evolv<strong>in</strong>g, if contested, body of <strong>in</strong>ternational law (see, e.g.,Anaya 1996; Havemann 1999; Tully 2000); from an <strong>Indigenous</strong>perspective, <strong>in</strong> the priority <strong>and</strong> cont<strong>in</strong>uity of <strong>Indigenous</strong> ties tothe l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> the personhood that is substantially derivative of. Reported to me <strong>in</strong> Ottawa <strong>in</strong> January, 2003, by the second party to the conversation.See also Salée (1995) for further discussion of this issue <strong>in</strong> Canada.. The range of such work is enormous <strong>in</strong> all four countries. Illustrations <strong>and</strong>accounts can be found <strong>in</strong>, among many other places, Walker (1990), <strong>Indigenous</strong>Constitutional Convention Secretariat (c. 1999); Smith (1993); Cornell(1988a); Nagel (1996).


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>those ties, of shared cultural practice <strong>and</strong> of collective memory.Both perspectives support the right of <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples todeterm<strong>in</strong>e their own futures <strong>and</strong> control their own affairs.More specifically, this means the right to shape the political orderof which they are a part, from their relationship with encompass<strong>in</strong>gsocieties to the <strong>in</strong>stitutions by which they govern themselves—<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the laws to which they <strong>and</strong> others are subject <strong>in</strong> theirown l<strong>and</strong>s—<strong>and</strong> thereby to maximize their control over l<strong>and</strong>s<strong>and</strong> resources, cultural <strong>and</strong> civil affairs, <strong>and</strong> the nature <strong>and</strong> qualityof community life. These peoples have seldom sought, <strong>in</strong> recentdecades, complete separation from those encompass<strong>in</strong>g societies.Instead, they generally have envisioned “nations with<strong>in</strong>” status(Fleras <strong>and</strong> Elliott 1992), or what Anaya (1996: 112) describesas “on the one h<strong>and</strong> autonomy <strong>and</strong> on the other participatoryengagement” <strong>in</strong> the encompass<strong>in</strong>g whole, an arrangement <strong>in</strong> which<strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples “are appropriately viewed as simultaneouslydist<strong>in</strong>ct from yet parts of larger units of social <strong>and</strong> political<strong>in</strong>teraction” (see also Behrendt 2001; S<strong>and</strong>ers 2002).The outcomes of their efforts have varied across these cases.<strong>Indigenous</strong> groups have won some battles <strong>in</strong> pursuit of these ends,lead<strong>in</strong>g to policy changes of various k<strong>in</strong>ds, to exp<strong>and</strong>ed <strong>Indigenous</strong>self-rule with<strong>in</strong> limited policy doma<strong>in</strong>s, to an <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>Indigenous</strong>voice <strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> political affairs, <strong>and</strong> to the return of some l<strong>and</strong>s<strong>and</strong> other resources. Other battles, however, have been lost, <strong>and</strong>the most fundamental issues of status <strong>and</strong> rights rema<strong>in</strong>, <strong>in</strong> allfour cases, substantially unresolved. . Anaya (1996: 81) describes self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation as consist<strong>in</strong>g of “two normativestra<strong>in</strong>s: First, <strong>in</strong> what may be called its constitutive aspect, self-determ<strong>in</strong>ationrequires that the govern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutional order be substantially the creationof processes guided by the will of the people, or peoples, governed. Second,<strong>in</strong> what may be called its ongo<strong>in</strong>g aspect, self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation requires that thegovern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutional order, <strong>in</strong>dependently of the processes lead<strong>in</strong>g to itscreation or alteration, be one under which people may live <strong>and</strong> develop freelyon a cont<strong>in</strong>uous basis.”. The literature on <strong>in</strong>digenous status <strong>and</strong> rights <strong>in</strong> these societies is vast, but


CornellCentral governments, on the other h<strong>and</strong>, as illustrated by theCanadian case, have been reluctant to engage with the issuesthat form the core of <strong>Indigenous</strong> concerns. They have preferredto focus on the socio-economics of <strong>in</strong>tegration <strong>and</strong> typicallyhave <strong>in</strong>terpreted self-government as an adm<strong>in</strong>istrative project <strong>in</strong>which <strong>Indigenous</strong> populations are allowed to manage programsdesigned—usually by central governments—to address socialproblems <strong>and</strong> economic marg<strong>in</strong>ality.In <strong>Australia</strong>, for example, Smith (2002: 3) observes that “<strong>in</strong> recentyears self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation… has been rejected as an active federalgovernment policy position.” Accord<strong>in</strong>g to S<strong>and</strong>ers (2002: 2),the current government “has preferred to focus its rhetoric on‘practical’ matters such as ‘overcom<strong>in</strong>g disadvantage’ <strong>and</strong> achiev<strong>in</strong>gbetter ‘outcomes’ for <strong>Indigenous</strong> people <strong>in</strong> areas like employment,hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> health, while seem<strong>in</strong>gly studiously avoid<strong>in</strong>g anyreference to self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation…” (see also Dodson <strong>and</strong> Pritchard1998).Similarly, recent government policy <strong>in</strong> New Zeal<strong>and</strong>, whilepay<strong>in</strong>g some lip-service to the idea of self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation, has beenconcerned primarily with “clos<strong>in</strong>g the gaps” <strong>and</strong> for a time evenadopted this as its official policy slogan. “Clos<strong>in</strong>g the Gaps,” remarksLoomis (2000: 11), “means improv<strong>in</strong>g ma<strong>in</strong>stream governmentservices <strong>and</strong> target<strong>in</strong>g fund<strong>in</strong>g to Maori provider groups. In effect,better State <strong>in</strong>tervention.” Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Humpage (2002: 45-6),the thrust of Maori affairs policy “has been the state’s desire toma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> protect its own legitimacy from potential threats,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g Maori calls for self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation focused on theestablishment of autonomous <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>and</strong> shared governancearrangements at the national level.” She goes on to po<strong>in</strong>t out thatsee, for example, Ivison, et al. (2000); Ivison (2002, 2003); Arthur (2001);S<strong>and</strong>ers (2002); Nettheim, et al. (2002); Fleras <strong>and</strong> Spoonley (1999); Durie(2000); Price (2001); Royal Commission on Aborig<strong>in</strong>al <strong>Peoples</strong> (1996); Mc-Neil (1998); Mohawk Council of Akwesasne (2002); Getches (2001); Wilk<strong>in</strong>s(2002); Cornell, et al. (2002).


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>“distributive justice, needs <strong>and</strong> development discourses have beenused to support this preference for conf<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Maori claims tothe domestic, dependent rights of citizenship…. Each of thesediscourses def<strong>in</strong>es the ‘problem’ largely <strong>in</strong> terms of Maori socioeconomicstatus” (see also Maaka <strong>and</strong> Fleras 2000).The exception to this pattern would seem to be, superficially at least,the United States. In the mid-1970s, <strong>in</strong> response to a nationwidemovement of Indian political activism <strong>and</strong> aggressive dem<strong>and</strong>s byIndian nations for greater self-government <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>creased controlover l<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> other resources, the U.S. government adopted apolicy commonly known as “self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation.” This policy, atleast on paper, acknowledged the right of Indian nations to decidefor themselves what was best for them.The rhetoric of self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation, however, outstripped thereality. Despite the name, this was not self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>in</strong>the classic sense. The <strong>in</strong>tent was not to give Indian nations thepower to reshape the political order either with<strong>in</strong> tribes or <strong>in</strong> theirrelations with the United States. What policy-makers had <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>dwas more modest: a shift from federal bureaucrats to tribal ones<strong>in</strong> adm<strong>in</strong>istrative authority over federal socio-economic supportprograms (see Barsh <strong>and</strong> Trosper 1975; Deloria <strong>and</strong> Lytle 1983;Esber 1992). In other words, the federal idea was to treat selfgovernmentas self-adm<strong>in</strong>istration, turn<strong>in</strong>g tribal governments<strong>in</strong>to adjuncts of the federal adm<strong>in</strong>istrative apparatus. In the yearss<strong>in</strong>ce, most federal <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>in</strong> Indian affairs has been moreconcerned with address<strong>in</strong>g social problems than with build<strong>in</strong>g<strong>Indigenous</strong> capacities for genu<strong>in</strong>e self-rule. This trend has beensupported by recent U.S. court decisions that have severelycurtailed tribal jurisdiction <strong>and</strong> underm<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>Indigenous</strong> rights ofself-government (Getches 2001; Wilk<strong>in</strong>s 2002).In sum, central governments have tended to respond to <strong>Indigenous</strong>peoples <strong>in</strong> the same ways they have responded to immigrant <strong>and</strong>other m<strong>in</strong>ority populations: with egalitarian <strong>and</strong> assimilativepolicies that attempt to address <strong>Indigenous</strong> disadvantage <strong>and</strong>facilitate <strong>in</strong>tegration <strong>in</strong>to encompass<strong>in</strong>g societies. In particular, the10


Cornellstark discrepancy between <strong>Indigenous</strong> socio-economic <strong>in</strong>dicators<strong>and</strong> those of the society at large has been a matter of recurrentpolicy concern, generat<strong>in</strong>g a diverse array of <strong>in</strong>itiatives designed tobr<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>in</strong>dicators more <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the ma<strong>in</strong>stream. 10Thus there is a significant mismatch between the ambitions of<strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples <strong>and</strong> the responses of states. States generallyhave been more will<strong>in</strong>g to engage with socio-economic issues ofequity <strong>and</strong> access than the political issues of self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation<strong>and</strong> difference that often have mattered more to <strong>Indigenous</strong>peoples. 11It is not difficult to underst<strong>and</strong> why. As Fleras (1999: 188) remarks,“At stake <strong>in</strong> the ethno-politics of <strong>in</strong>digeneity are fundamentalchallenges to the conventions <strong>and</strong> tacit assumptions that underp<strong>in</strong>the governance of White-settler dom<strong>in</strong>ions.” <strong>Indigenous</strong> selfdeterm<strong>in</strong>ationchallenges state concerns about societal cohesion<strong>and</strong> universality (“we are all the same”). In cases where <strong>Indigenous</strong>peoples potentially control significant natural resources, it threatensthe ability of the state to utilize those resources or facilitate theirmovement onto the market; <strong>and</strong> it generally underm<strong>in</strong>es the state’sability to tightly control either what happens with<strong>in</strong> its borders orthe political order itself, forc<strong>in</strong>g the state to consider—<strong>in</strong> at leastsome areas of political structure—a decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g partnership.10. Such policies have had decidedly mixed results <strong>in</strong> all four countries. Forexample, while considerable progress has been made <strong>in</strong> some areas, such ascerta<strong>in</strong> aspects of <strong>in</strong>digenous health, much less has been made aga<strong>in</strong>st the moregeneral phenomenon of <strong>in</strong>digenous poverty.11. In draw<strong>in</strong>g a dist<strong>in</strong>ction between <strong>in</strong>digenous assertions <strong>and</strong> state response,I do not mean to suggest that <strong>in</strong>digenous peoples have been un<strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong>equity or <strong>in</strong> address<strong>in</strong>g the grim realities of poverty. But <strong>in</strong>digenous politics <strong>in</strong>all four countries have tended to be recognitive first <strong>and</strong> distributive second.While there are exceptions, particularly among urban populations, rightsto l<strong>and</strong>, recognition <strong>and</strong> self-government have tended to take priority oversocio-economic issues. This has dist<strong>in</strong>guished much <strong>in</strong>digenous politics fromthe more distributive politics of immigrant groups or other, non-<strong>in</strong>digenousm<strong>in</strong>ority populations.11


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>As a result, <strong>and</strong> as Humpage (2002: 85) po<strong>in</strong>ts out <strong>in</strong> regard toNew Zeal<strong>and</strong>, central governments concerned with <strong>Indigenous</strong>issues have moved towards a rhetoric of distributive justice, “whichfocuses on the narrow <strong>in</strong>terest of redistribut<strong>in</strong>g socio-economicgoods,” <strong>and</strong> a needs-based discussion that positions <strong>Indigenous</strong>persons “as disadvantaged citizens who need ‘help’ <strong>in</strong> achiev<strong>in</strong>ga similar socio-economic status” to non-<strong>Indigenous</strong> persons. Inshort, reluctant to address <strong>Indigenous</strong> self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation, states<strong>in</strong>stead address <strong>Indigenous</strong> poverty.But what if the two are connected? What if self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation isa necessary element <strong>in</strong> the struggle aga<strong>in</strong>st poverty? In fact, thereis compell<strong>in</strong>g evidence from at least one case—American Indiannations <strong>in</strong> the United States—that these two sets of issues arerelated <strong>in</strong> practical <strong>and</strong> concrete terms.<strong>Indigenous</strong> poverty <strong>and</strong>self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation: the U.S. caseThe pattern of American Indian povertyThe <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples of the United States—commonlyknown to themselves <strong>and</strong> others as American Indians or NativeAmericans—are among the country’s poorest citizens. AmericanIndian reservations, as the reserved l<strong>and</strong>s belong<strong>in</strong>g to Indiannations are called, <strong>in</strong>clude a number of America’s poorestplaces, <strong>and</strong> reservation-based populations rank at the bottom,or near the bottom, of the scale of <strong>in</strong>come, employment, health,hous<strong>in</strong>g, education <strong>and</strong> other <strong>in</strong>dices of poverty (Henson et al.forthcom<strong>in</strong>g).Strik<strong>in</strong>gly, however, this situation is not uniform across Indiannations. In the last quarter or so of the twentieth century, someIndian nations began do<strong>in</strong>g significantly better than others,build<strong>in</strong>g susta<strong>in</strong>able economies that fitted their own strategies<strong>and</strong> criteria of economic success. Furthermore, this uneven patternof economic performance is not easily expla<strong>in</strong>ed by many of the12


Cornellusual economic factors such as natural resource endowments,educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment or location, which vary widely across themore successful of these nations. Nor is the pattern easily expla<strong>in</strong>edby <strong>in</strong>ternal colonialism or dependency. While their histories of<strong>in</strong>teraction with the colonial power have varied, Indian nations<strong>in</strong> the United States, exclud<strong>in</strong>g Alaska, have been subject to abroadly similar regime of legal <strong>and</strong> political dom<strong>in</strong>ation. 12 Thatregime readily accounts for their descent <strong>in</strong>to poverty, but not fordifferential success <strong>in</strong> escap<strong>in</strong>g poverty.Expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the patternIn the mid-1980s, the Harvard Project on American IndianEconomic Development began a research effort designed toexpla<strong>in</strong> the emerg<strong>in</strong>g pattern of <strong>Indigenous</strong> economic success.What was enabl<strong>in</strong>g some Indian nations to break away from theoverall pattern of seem<strong>in</strong>gly <strong>in</strong>tractable poverty? What were theconditions for susta<strong>in</strong>ed economic development on AmericanIndian reservations?This research effort, cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g today through the HarvardProject <strong>and</strong> its sister organization, the Native Nations Institute forLeadership, Management, <strong>and</strong> Policy at the University of Arizona,has produced results with policy-significant implications. Acrossa sample of nearly seventy Indian nations, the most consistentpredictors of susta<strong>in</strong>able economic development on Indianreservations are not economic factors such as location, educationalatta<strong>in</strong>ment or natural resource endowments but rather largelypolitical ones. Three have proven particularly important.• Sovereignty or self-rule. <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples have to havegenu<strong>in</strong>e decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g power <strong>in</strong> their own h<strong>and</strong>s, fromconstitution-mak<strong>in</strong>g to law-mak<strong>in</strong>g to policy. The primaryreason for this is accountability: it l<strong>in</strong>ks decision-makers <strong>and</strong>the consequences of their decisions.12. On Alaska, see Case <strong>and</strong> Voluck (2002), Berger (1985), <strong>and</strong> Cornell <strong>and</strong>Kalt (2003).13


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>• Capable govern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions. <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples have to beable to exercise decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g power effectively. Do<strong>in</strong>g sorequires <strong>in</strong>stitutional stability, depoliticized dispute resolutionmechanisms such as tribal courts, depoliticized managementof resources <strong>and</strong> enterprises, skilled adm<strong>in</strong>istration, <strong>and</strong> otherprovisions. These create an environment of governmentalaction that is stable, fair, competent <strong>and</strong> reliable, shift<strong>in</strong>g thefocus of government towards nation-build<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> away fromfactional battles over resources. 13• A congruence between formal govern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>and</strong><strong>Indigenous</strong> political culture. There has to be a match betweenthe formal <strong>in</strong>stitutions of governance <strong>and</strong> prevail<strong>in</strong>g ideaswith<strong>in</strong> the community or nation about how authority shouldbe organized <strong>and</strong> exercised. This cultural match is the sourceof government’s legitimacy with those be<strong>in</strong>g governed, <strong>and</strong>therefore a source of its effectiveness (see Lipset 1963). Oneof the h<strong>and</strong>icaps fac<strong>in</strong>g American Indian nations has beenthe stark mismatch between <strong>Indigenous</strong> social <strong>and</strong> politicalorganization on the one h<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong>, on the other, an imposedoverlay of govern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions designed largely by the U.S.government <strong>in</strong> the 1930s. This has tended to produce tribalgovernments that lack support with their own citizens, havedifficulty gett<strong>in</strong>g th<strong>in</strong>gs done, <strong>and</strong> easily become objects ofpolitical opportunism <strong>and</strong> factional conflict.Where these three factors are <strong>in</strong> place, community assets—fromnatural resources to location to human capital—beg<strong>in</strong> to pay off.Where they are miss<strong>in</strong>g, such assets are typically squ<strong>and</strong>eredor fail to yield their potential. In short, it is the political factorswhich either limit or release the potential of economic <strong>and</strong> otherassets. 1413. The idea that govern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions matter to economic performance <strong>and</strong>societal well-be<strong>in</strong>g is well-established. See, for example, North (1990),;Oberschall(1990); Barro (1991); Ostrom (1992); Knack <strong>and</strong> Keefer (1995); Egnal(1996); <strong>and</strong> La Porta et al. (1997, 1998, 1999).14. For these results, see <strong>in</strong> particular Cornell <strong>and</strong> Kalt (1992, 1995, 1997a,14


CornellThe mean<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> role of self-ruleThe first of these factors—sovereignty or self-rule—is of critical<strong>in</strong>terest to this discussion. Sovereignty or self-rule appears to be anecessary, but not sufficient, condition for susta<strong>in</strong>able developmenton <strong>Indigenous</strong> l<strong>and</strong>s.I say “sovereignty or self-rule” because of the ideas of exclusivity<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>divisibility often attached to the term “sovereignty.” Theprotection <strong>and</strong> expansion of “tribal sovereignty” have long beencentral political objectives of American Indian nations, but theterm has not necessarily implied separate statehood or absoluteauthority vested <strong>in</strong> Indian h<strong>and</strong>s. On the contrary, its commonusage <strong>in</strong> Indian politics has tended to accommodate the possibilityof a shared or limited sovereignty, a usage that has roots <strong>in</strong>, amongother places, the Marshall trilogy of U.S. Supreme Court decisions<strong>in</strong> the 1820s <strong>and</strong> early 1830s that described Indian societies asdomestic dependent nations that, nonetheless, rema<strong>in</strong>ed dist<strong>in</strong>ctpolitical communities <strong>and</strong> reta<strong>in</strong>ed exclusive authority with<strong>in</strong> theirterritories. 15 With<strong>in</strong> this usage, one can imag<strong>in</strong>e a sovereignty thatis flexible both <strong>in</strong> the degree <strong>and</strong> the scope of authority across<strong>in</strong>stitutional or policy doma<strong>in</strong>s <strong>and</strong> that is tailored to supporta particular relationship between peoples or nations. In somedoma<strong>in</strong>s it may be an exclusive sovereignty; <strong>in</strong> some, it may beshared. Sovereignty thus becomes a cont<strong>in</strong>uous as opposed to adichotomous variable. 161997b, 2000, 2003); also Krepps <strong>and</strong> Caves (1994); Jorgensen (2000a); Jorgensen<strong>and</strong> Taylor (2000); Jorgensen et al. (forthcom<strong>in</strong>g); <strong>and</strong> Harvard Projecton American Indian Economic Development (1999, 2000, 2003).15. Cherokee Nation v. Georgia, 30 U.S. (5 Pet.) 1 (1831); Worcester v.Georgia, 31 U.S. (6 Pet.) 515 (1832). See the discussion of these decisions <strong>in</strong>Deloria <strong>and</strong> Lytle (1983).16. See the discussion of sovereignty <strong>in</strong> Maaka <strong>and</strong> Fleras (2000: 92-4) <strong>and</strong> ofdevolution <strong>in</strong> Smith (2002: 3-5).15


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>This usage, however, is less common outside the United States,where sovereignty often is viewed <strong>in</strong> zero-sum terms: to theextent that “we” have it, “you” don’t. 17 The term self-rule, on theother h<strong>and</strong>, appears to carry less def<strong>in</strong>itional baggage.In any case, the core question from a development viewpo<strong>in</strong>t issimple <strong>and</strong> can be phrased <strong>in</strong> a number of ways: Who controlsthe primary relationships <strong>in</strong>volved? Who is exercis<strong>in</strong>g decisionmak<strong>in</strong>gpower? Who is call<strong>in</strong>g the shots with<strong>in</strong> a given policydoma<strong>in</strong> or set of decisions? Who’s <strong>in</strong> charge? To the degree thatthe answer to such questions is the <strong>Indigenous</strong> nation, this is anexample of <strong>Indigenous</strong> self-rule. To the degree that the answer issomeone else, it is the absence of self-rule.The U.S. research noted above shows that as Indian nationsexp<strong>and</strong> the scope <strong>and</strong> degree of their own decision-mak<strong>in</strong>gpower, the chances of susta<strong>in</strong>able economic development rise.This is particularly so <strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> doma<strong>in</strong>s such as constitutionalauthority, the design of govern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions, law-mak<strong>in</strong>g, themanagement of l<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> resources, the organization of civilsociety, <strong>and</strong> the determ<strong>in</strong>ation of strategies for community <strong>and</strong>economic development. In such areas, the likelihood of achiev<strong>in</strong>gsusta<strong>in</strong>able development rises as power <strong>and</strong> authority are devolvedto <strong>Indigenous</strong> nations or communities, mov<strong>in</strong>g non-<strong>Indigenous</strong>entities, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g central governments, from decision-mak<strong>in</strong>gto resource roles <strong>and</strong> free<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples to decide theseth<strong>in</strong>gs for themselves <strong>and</strong> by their own criteria.Admittedly, the shift <strong>in</strong> jurisdictional power is <strong>in</strong> itself no guaranteeof susta<strong>in</strong>able development; it merely makes such developmentpossible. As the research results summarized above <strong>in</strong>dicate, more17. See Tully (2000: 51), who describes this view as hold<strong>in</strong>g that “either thedom<strong>in</strong>ant state exercises exclusive jurisdiction or the <strong>in</strong>digenous people do,”with no middle ground. Label<strong>in</strong>g this as one of the “underly<strong>in</strong>g presumptions”that states use “to legitimize the system of <strong>in</strong>ternal colonization,” he notes thatit ignores the possibility that “jurisdiction can be shared.”16


Cornellis needed. Those nations mak<strong>in</strong>g the decisions have to be capableof govern<strong>in</strong>g well. They have to put <strong>in</strong> place an <strong>in</strong>stitutionalenvironment that their citizens support <strong>and</strong> which can encourage<strong>and</strong> susta<strong>in</strong> economic activity <strong>and</strong> community <strong>in</strong>itiatives that fittheir strategic objectives <strong>and</strong> opportunities. But self-rule itselfrema<strong>in</strong>s essential. Jurisdiction that is not backed up by effectivegovern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions will be unproductive, but a set of welldesignedgovern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions that lack jurisdictional authoritywill be toothless. In either case, the result will be someth<strong>in</strong>g otherthan susta<strong>in</strong>able development.Why does self-rule play such a large role <strong>in</strong> produc<strong>in</strong>g theseeffects? There are several reasons. First, with self-rule, decisionmak<strong>in</strong>greflects <strong>Indigenous</strong> agendas <strong>and</strong> knowledge, mak<strong>in</strong>g itmore likely that solutions to problems will be appropriate <strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>formed <strong>and</strong>, therefore, viable. Second, it puts developmentresources <strong>in</strong> <strong>Indigenous</strong> h<strong>and</strong>s, allow<strong>in</strong>g a more efficient use ofthose resources to meet <strong>Indigenous</strong> objectives. Third, it fosterscitizen engagement <strong>in</strong> economic <strong>and</strong> community development,someth<strong>in</strong>g effectively discouraged—with the attendant humanenergy be<strong>in</strong>g wasted—when the nation lacks substantive power.Fourth—<strong>and</strong> most importantly—it shifts accountability.Devolution makes governmental decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g accountableto those most directly affected. The decision-makers themselvespay the price of bad decisions <strong>and</strong> reap the benefits of good ones.Consequently, <strong>and</strong> allow<strong>in</strong>g time for a learn<strong>in</strong>g curve, decisionquality improves. For generations, authority over <strong>Indigenous</strong>peoples not only <strong>in</strong> the U.S. but <strong>in</strong> <strong>Australia</strong>, New Zeal<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong>Canada has rested with non-<strong>Indigenous</strong> governments, which haveseldom been held accountable to the <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples they havegoverned. This divorce between those with the authority to makedecisions <strong>and</strong> those bear<strong>in</strong>g the consequences of those decisionshas resulted <strong>in</strong> an extraord<strong>in</strong>ary <strong>and</strong> cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g record of centralgovernment policy failure <strong>in</strong> all four countries.17


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong><strong>Self</strong>-determ<strong>in</strong>ation as an anti-poverty policyAs already noted, when the U.S. moved to the “self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation”policy, its <strong>in</strong>tent was modest: to br<strong>in</strong>g Indian nations <strong>in</strong>to theadm<strong>in</strong>istration of federal programs <strong>and</strong> quash Indian compla<strong>in</strong>tsabout lack of <strong>in</strong>put. But with the federal government on thedefensive, <strong>and</strong> presented with a policy that paid at least lipservice to the idea of tribal control over tribal futures, manyIndian nations moved quickly to assert self-govern<strong>in</strong>g powers,variously redesign<strong>in</strong>g govern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions previously designedby outsiders, tak<strong>in</strong>g over management of resources, retool<strong>in</strong>gdevelopment strategies, <strong>and</strong> displac<strong>in</strong>g federal decision-makers <strong>in</strong>an assortment of reservation matters. Some of these assertionswere confrontational. Others unfolded <strong>in</strong>crementally as triballeaders took the <strong>in</strong>itiative <strong>in</strong> governmental reorganization <strong>and</strong>constitutional reform, searched for alternative fund<strong>in</strong>g sourcesthrough bus<strong>in</strong>ess enterprises, excluded federal representativesfrom decision processes, stopped ask<strong>in</strong>g permission before act<strong>in</strong>g,<strong>and</strong> filled the governmental gaps left by <strong>in</strong>adequate, <strong>in</strong>competentor paternalistic federal adm<strong>in</strong>istration.As they did so, those nations that also backed up their assertedpowers with effective <strong>and</strong> culturally congruent govern<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>stitutions began to see significant results. Among these werereduced unemployment, reduced welfare rolls, the emergenceof viable <strong>and</strong> diverse economic enterprises—both tribal <strong>and</strong>private—on reservation l<strong>and</strong>s, more effective adm<strong>in</strong>istration ofsocial services <strong>and</strong> programs, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g those address<strong>in</strong>g language<strong>and</strong> cultural concerns, <strong>and</strong> improved management of naturalresources. In case after case, such nations proved to be much betterat runn<strong>in</strong>g their own affairs <strong>and</strong> manag<strong>in</strong>g their own resourcesthan federal adm<strong>in</strong>istrators had ever been. 1818. Cornell <strong>and</strong> Kalt (1992, 1998); Cornell et al. (1998); Jorgensen (1997,2000b); Jorgensen <strong>and</strong> Taylor (2000); Krepps (1992); Krepps <strong>and</strong> Caves(1994); Wakel<strong>in</strong>g et al. (2001); Harvard Project on American Indian EconomicDevelopment (1999, 2000, 2003).18


CornellThe U.S. government had <strong>in</strong>advertently stumbled on the onlypolicy that—<strong>in</strong> three-quarters of a century of federal attemptsto improve socio-economic conditions on American Indianreservations—actually made significant progress aga<strong>in</strong>streservation poverty. While the United States may not have<strong>in</strong>tended the “self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation” policy launched <strong>in</strong> the 1970s to<strong>in</strong>clude constitutional authority <strong>and</strong> exp<strong>and</strong>ed tribal jurisdiction,a number of Indian nations chose to <strong>in</strong>terpret it that way <strong>and</strong>benefited enormously from do<strong>in</strong>g so. <strong>Self</strong>-determ<strong>in</strong>ation, itturned out, was an effective anti-poverty policy—the first ever <strong>in</strong>U.S. relations with Indian nations.The transferability of U.S. resultsThe American Indian experience connects self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation<strong>and</strong> self-governance with overcom<strong>in</strong>g poverty. It argues that theway to attack socio-economic disadvantage among <strong>Indigenous</strong>peoples is not primarily by organiz<strong>in</strong>g centrally designedprograms address<strong>in</strong>g poverty <strong>and</strong> its related social pathologies—although such programs can provide tribes with needed resources<strong>and</strong> expertise—but <strong>in</strong>stead by substantially exp<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g thejurisdictional authority of those nations <strong>and</strong> empower<strong>in</strong>g themto develop capable govern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions that <strong>in</strong> turn can supportsusta<strong>in</strong>able, self-determ<strong>in</strong>ed economies <strong>and</strong> social programs oftheir own design. Noth<strong>in</strong>g else has worked.But how generalizable is the U.S. case? Can it be extendedto <strong>Australia</strong>, New Zeal<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Canada? Could exp<strong>and</strong>edjurisdiction <strong>and</strong> constitutional authority, backed up by effective<strong>and</strong> culturally congruent govern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions, yield comparableresults <strong>in</strong> <strong>Indigenous</strong> economic <strong>and</strong> community well-be<strong>in</strong>g?19


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>Only systematic research can answer such questions def<strong>in</strong>itively, 19but I see little theoretical basis for believ<strong>in</strong>g the U.S. resultsare <strong>in</strong>applicable to these other situations. Specific developmentoutcomes obviously depend on other factors as well, however,<strong>and</strong> the translation of these results <strong>in</strong>to practical policy <strong>in</strong>itiatives<strong>in</strong> other countries will require careful consideration of specific<strong>Indigenous</strong> situations. At least three issues appear to be important:the economic circumstances of various <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples; theproblem of identify<strong>in</strong>g appropriate units of collective authority;<strong>and</strong> the will<strong>in</strong>gness of ma<strong>in</strong>stream societies to tolerate difference<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> <strong>Indigenous</strong> capacities. I consider the first two ofthese here <strong>and</strong> the last <strong>in</strong> the conclud<strong>in</strong>g section of this paper.Economic circumstancesWith<strong>in</strong>-country variation <strong>in</strong> economic resources <strong>and</strong> opportunitiesobviously has major impacts on the development potential of<strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples. To pick an obvious <strong>and</strong> extreme U.S. example,Indian <strong>and</strong> Eskimo nations located <strong>in</strong> remote regions of Alaska oron very small l<strong>and</strong> bases face narrower economic opportunity setsthan those faced by Indian nations located near large metropolitanareas or on large l<strong>and</strong> bases. Similarly, variation <strong>in</strong> human capitalcan affect the ability of <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples to take advantageof certa<strong>in</strong> k<strong>in</strong>ds of opportunities—or at least delay action <strong>in</strong>response to those opportunities while human capital <strong>in</strong>vestmentsare made.Such variation is apparent <strong>in</strong> all four countries. Many First Nations<strong>in</strong> Canada have been left with m<strong>in</strong>uscule l<strong>and</strong> bases, or are locatedfar from markets <strong>and</strong> transportation systems. Many <strong>Australia</strong>nAborig<strong>in</strong>al communities are remote. The circumstances of Maoripeoples likewise vary across the country. Some groups have higherlevels of education or labor force experience than others.19. Such research has begun <strong>in</strong> Canada <strong>and</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ds evidence of similar relationships.See Jorgensen et al. (forthcom<strong>in</strong>g); also Ch<strong>and</strong>ler <strong>and</strong> Lalonde (1998),<strong>and</strong> Moore, et al. (1990).20


CornellSuch variation does not negate the U.S. results; it is apparent <strong>in</strong> theU.S. as well. <strong>Self</strong>-determ<strong>in</strong>ation, self-governance <strong>and</strong> appropriate<strong>and</strong> effective govern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions create an environment <strong>in</strong>which susta<strong>in</strong>able development becomes possible, but the nature<strong>and</strong> extent of development <strong>and</strong> of its impact on the communitydepend on what each <strong>Indigenous</strong> nation or people has to workwith <strong>and</strong> on the specific decisions it makes. What the U.S. case<strong>in</strong>dicates is that economic assets—whatever they may be—arefar more likely to be productive where <strong>Indigenous</strong> nations havedecision-mak<strong>in</strong>g power <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>stitutional capacity to back itup.The social unit of authorityBut where should decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g power <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutionalcapacity be located? <strong>Self</strong>-determ<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>and</strong> self-governancerequire subjects, <strong>in</strong> the grammatical sense: someone has to do thedeterm<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> govern<strong>in</strong>g. In which social units do the rights toself-determ<strong>in</strong>ation reside? With<strong>in</strong> which social units should the<strong>in</strong>stitutions of self-governance be built? Who, <strong>in</strong> these processes,is the “self ”?In all four countries, one of the most prom<strong>in</strong>ent results of a centuryor more of colonialism, l<strong>and</strong> expropriation, ethnic cleans<strong>in</strong>g,imposed population movements, assimilationist programs, <strong>and</strong>related settler-state policies has been the transformation of<strong>Indigenous</strong> group boundaries, many of which already were porous<strong>and</strong> dynamic long before European contact. Some collectivitiesdisappeared while others were mixed or fragmented; someboundaries were <strong>in</strong>vented out of whole cloth while others weresolidified out of pre-exist<strong>in</strong>g relationships.While these processes were common <strong>in</strong> the United States, theparticular form they have taken there has provided, <strong>in</strong> most cases,unusual clarity about the identity of the “self ”. Despite urbanization<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>termarriage among American Indian groups, tribal societieshave cont<strong>in</strong>ued to exist <strong>and</strong>, <strong>in</strong> some cases, thrive on Indianreservations. While warfare, colonialism, <strong>and</strong> assimilationistprograms came close to ext<strong>in</strong>guish<strong>in</strong>g the Indian l<strong>and</strong> base,21


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>the remnant parcels, some of them substantial, have comb<strong>in</strong>edwith the treaty process <strong>and</strong> the peculiarities of federal Indianadm<strong>in</strong>istration to simplify <strong>and</strong> rigidify <strong>in</strong>ter-group boundariesthat previously had been more complex or fluid. Although thisprocess often ignored <strong>Indigenous</strong> perceptions, it un<strong>in</strong>tentionallyprovided a foundation for tribal cont<strong>in</strong>uity <strong>and</strong> survival (Cornell1988b).Today, both as political units <strong>and</strong> as frameworks of collectiveidentity, most Indian nations rema<strong>in</strong> robust. The “self ” <strong>in</strong> selfgovernance,has <strong>in</strong> most cases been apparent, embedded both <strong>in</strong>cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g social relations <strong>and</strong> cultural practice <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> formalpolitical relationships established by treaty between <strong>in</strong>dividualIndian nations <strong>and</strong> the United States. This clarifies whereconstitutional authority <strong>and</strong> jurisdiction should be vested <strong>and</strong>focuses the challenge of nation build<strong>in</strong>g. 20The situation has been more variable <strong>in</strong> the other three countries.A recurr<strong>in</strong>g concern <strong>in</strong> <strong>Australia</strong>, for example, accord<strong>in</strong>g to Bern<strong>and</strong> Dodds (2000: 163), “is how <strong>in</strong>digenous self-government<strong>and</strong> representation should be structured, given the array of goalsthat self-government is supposed to meet, <strong>and</strong> the diversity ofAborig<strong>in</strong>al communities.” Much of the organizational structureof <strong>in</strong>ter-group relations <strong>in</strong> <strong>Australia</strong> today is embedded <strong>in</strong> localor regional, federally funded, <strong>Indigenous</strong> service organizationsor <strong>in</strong> the national Aborig<strong>in</strong>al <strong>and</strong> Torres Strait Isl<strong>and</strong>erCommission (ATSIC). S<strong>and</strong>ers (2002) argues that both theservice organizations <strong>and</strong> ATSIC represent <strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>in</strong>terests,albeit different sets of <strong>in</strong>terests <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> different ways, but he alsoacknowledges that many local Aborig<strong>in</strong>al communities see neitherservice organizations nor an elected national body as adequatelyrepresent<strong>in</strong>g their concerns.20. Exceptions to this overall pattern <strong>in</strong>clude peoples forced together ontoreservations or <strong>in</strong>to shared treaty-mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> others fragmented by warfare,forced migration <strong>and</strong> other events. Both Alaska <strong>and</strong> California also <strong>in</strong>cludemany small Native groups located on small l<strong>and</strong> bases, limit<strong>in</strong>g human capitalpools <strong>and</strong> prompt<strong>in</strong>g debate about build<strong>in</strong>g jo<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong>stitutions of larger scale <strong>and</strong>broader jurisdiction.22


CornellBern <strong>and</strong> Dodds discuss the situation <strong>in</strong> the Northern Territory,where Aborig<strong>in</strong>al polity is constituted <strong>in</strong> three primary forms: l<strong>and</strong>councils, local communities, <strong>and</strong> k<strong>in</strong>ship/language groups. Onlythe last has traditional roots. Local communities “are largely basedon pastoral conta<strong>in</strong>ment <strong>and</strong>/or government/mission <strong>in</strong>stitutions,”while the l<strong>and</strong> councils are products of federal statute (2000:174). Only a few groups, particularly those with a geographicalbase or strong language ties, have been effective at organiz<strong>in</strong>g“above the level of the local community” (ibid.: 175). DavidMart<strong>in</strong> argues that <strong>in</strong> much of Cape York, “few if any <strong>Indigenous</strong>community-wide political <strong>in</strong>stitutions exist, apart from the quasilocalgovernment community councils <strong>in</strong>stituted under Statelegislation, <strong>and</strong> regional bodies…” (2001: 14). Many communitiesare products of enforced relocation to mission <strong>and</strong> governmentsettlements; the councils that have emerged <strong>in</strong> these situations,he claims, have “neither the political nor the moral authority”required for effective self-governance. Any new <strong>in</strong>stitutional orderwill require identify<strong>in</strong>g—<strong>and</strong> perhaps rebuild<strong>in</strong>g—“clear centresof political authority” (ibid.: 17) <strong>in</strong> these communities: a difficulttask. Meanwhile, Diane Smith (2002) <strong>and</strong> others argue for a“regionally dispersed, layered” system of self-governance <strong>in</strong> whichlocal communities are jurisdictional build<strong>in</strong>g blocks, aggregatedfor certa<strong>in</strong> purposes <strong>in</strong>to larger structures.A different <strong>Indigenous</strong> history <strong>in</strong> New Zeal<strong>and</strong> has led to somesimilar issues. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the Maori historian Rang<strong>in</strong>ui Walker,prior to European <strong>in</strong>cursions the hapu, sometimes described asa clan, 21 was “the ma<strong>in</strong> political unit that controlled a def<strong>in</strong>edstretch of tribal territory” (1990: 64). Angela Ballara (1998) has21. Walker (1990: 63-5) identifies three basic units of Maori society: thewhanau is an extended family, the hapu is a descent group composed of relatedwhanau, <strong>and</strong> the iwi is a descent group composed of related hapu. Ballara(1998: 161) describes hapu as “politically <strong>in</strong>dependent corporate <strong>and</strong> socialgroups which also regarded themselves as categorically identified with a widerset of people.” Like Walker, she emphasizes the prom<strong>in</strong>ence of hapu, but shealso notes that this tripartite organization is neither as rigid nor as static as asimple description might imply (ibid.: 17-19).23


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>traced the historical processes that encouraged Maori to alter thispolitical structure. Such structures are generally dynamic, but theEuropean agenda shaped the process of change <strong>in</strong> particular ways.Negotiat<strong>in</strong>g over l<strong>and</strong>, Europeans searched for <strong>and</strong> encouragedparamount chiefs at ever larger scales of social organization.Maori responded to l<strong>and</strong> pressure <strong>in</strong> part by comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> largerunits to defend their <strong>in</strong>terests. Over time, both Europeans <strong>and</strong>Maori tended to construct Maori—for purposes of <strong>in</strong>tergrouprelations—<strong>in</strong> fewer <strong>and</strong> larger social groups. The result was toprivilege iwi, (conceived as peoples, tribes or confederations ofhapu), over hapu. Formal government policy <strong>and</strong> the organizationof social programs have tended to cont<strong>in</strong>ue the trend <strong>in</strong> recentyears, lead<strong>in</strong>g to what Manuhuia Barcham (2000: 141) calls “theiwi-isation of Maori society.”But the situation is further complicated by cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>gdiversification. A majority of Maori now live <strong>in</strong> cities. Alongwith the more general <strong>in</strong>tegration of many Maori <strong>in</strong>to NewZeal<strong>and</strong> society, this has produced new sets of <strong>in</strong>terests that donot easily comb<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>to hapu or iwi constructions. Speak<strong>in</strong>g ofthe Maori concept of t<strong>in</strong>o rangatiratanga, a polysemous conceptthat comb<strong>in</strong>es ideas of, among other th<strong>in</strong>gs, sovereignty, selfdeterm<strong>in</strong>ation,autonomy, nationhood, <strong>and</strong> chiefta<strong>in</strong>ship, Maaka<strong>and</strong> Fleras remark that “for some, t<strong>in</strong>o rangatiratanga resideswith<strong>in</strong> the hapu; for others, the iwi; for still others only Maori asa collectivity; <strong>and</strong> for yet others still, with<strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dividual” (2000:100). Under these conditions, what form should self-governmenttake?In Canada, as <strong>in</strong> the United States, a lengthy history of treatymak<strong>in</strong>g,l<strong>and</strong> loss, <strong>and</strong> paternalistic federal adm<strong>in</strong>istration hasreshaped Aborig<strong>in</strong>al political relationships <strong>and</strong> group boundaries.Particularly under the Indian Act of 1876 <strong>and</strong> its subsequentamendments, the government of Canada recognized variousgroups of Aborig<strong>in</strong>al people as b<strong>and</strong>s, recognized certa<strong>in</strong> l<strong>and</strong>s asreserved to those b<strong>and</strong>s, replaced <strong>Indigenous</strong> governmental forms<strong>and</strong> practices with imposed ones, <strong>and</strong>, on behalf of assimilationistgoals, regulated numerous aspects of Aborig<strong>in</strong>al life. While some24


Cornellgroup identities <strong>and</strong> boundaries supported by federal recognitionmade sense, others appear to have been chosen at the whim oflocal adm<strong>in</strong>istrators or to be simply the result of a dispersedgeography. 22 Widely distributed peoples shar<strong>in</strong>g culture <strong>and</strong>language often were broken up <strong>and</strong> isolated from each other <strong>in</strong>small numbers on t<strong>in</strong>y acreages. Their modest self-govern<strong>in</strong>gpowers were exercised through imposed <strong>in</strong>stitutions that had“no…congruence with the cultural premises of aborig<strong>in</strong>al people”(Scott 1993: 322). Today, Canada’s <strong>Indigenous</strong> population ismuch smaller, <strong>in</strong> absolute numbers, than the Indian population ofthe United States, but it is divided <strong>in</strong>to many more First Nationslocated on many more, <strong>and</strong> generally much smaller, reserves.In the 1990s, one of the major concerns of Canada’s RoyalCommission on Aborig<strong>in</strong>al <strong>Peoples</strong> was the effect of this historicallygenerated fragmentation on self-government. The commissionconcluded that some Aborig<strong>in</strong>al b<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> communities were toosmall to effectively exercise self-govern<strong>in</strong>g powers. “The problem,”said the commission, “is that the historical Aborig<strong>in</strong>al nationswere underm<strong>in</strong>ed by disease, relocations <strong>and</strong> the full array ofassimilationist government policies. They were fragmented <strong>in</strong>tob<strong>and</strong>s, reserves <strong>and</strong> small settlements. Only some operate ascollectivities now. They will have to reconstruct themselves asnations” (Royal Commission on Aborig<strong>in</strong>al <strong>Peoples</strong> 1996: 26). Itwent on to suggest that the thous<strong>and</strong> or so Aborig<strong>in</strong>al settlementsor reserve communities <strong>in</strong> Canada comprised only “60 to 80” suchnations, based on bonds of culture <strong>and</strong> identity (ibid.: 25). Whilesome Canadian First Nations would dispute those numbers <strong>and</strong>might see themselves differently, the underly<strong>in</strong>g issue rema<strong>in</strong>s:At what level of the social order should <strong>in</strong>stitution-build<strong>in</strong>gappropriately occur? Should it be <strong>in</strong> b<strong>and</strong>s, tribes, confederationsof tribes, or <strong>in</strong> different entities <strong>in</strong> different situations?22. There are similar cases <strong>in</strong> the U.S. but, thanks <strong>in</strong> part to differences <strong>in</strong> thetreaty process, they are less prevalent than <strong>in</strong> Canada.25


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>These legacies of colonialism <strong>and</strong> paternalism will not be easyto overcome. In many cases, f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g appropriate social units ofauthority will be complex <strong>and</strong> time-consum<strong>in</strong>g, but the fact thatsuch units are sometimes no longer obvious is not an argumentaga<strong>in</strong>st self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation. On the contrary, it should sharpen thefocus of both <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples <strong>and</strong> central governments on acritical first step <strong>in</strong> nation build<strong>in</strong>g. 23 In search<strong>in</strong>g for such units,several th<strong>in</strong>gs should be borne <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d. First, the outcome shouldbe home-grown. Imposed units are likely to be failed units.Second, the effort will take time. Rebuild<strong>in</strong>g a sense of nationhoodrequires not so much exhortation or deadl<strong>in</strong>es as it does carefuldeliberation <strong>and</strong> broad community participation. Third, both<strong>Indigenous</strong> leaders <strong>and</strong> central governments will have to wrestlewith two requirements of such units: they have to have legitimacywith the people they are go<strong>in</strong>g to govern, <strong>and</strong> they have to providean efficacious foundation for governance. Comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g legitimacy<strong>and</strong> efficacy is one of the major challenges of nation build<strong>in</strong>g.Conclusion: Policy implicationsThere is substantial evidence from the U.S. case that <strong>Indigenous</strong>self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation has been a critical element <strong>in</strong> the effort byAmerican Indian nations to improve their socio-economicconditions. While <strong>Indigenous</strong> situations <strong>in</strong> <strong>Australia</strong>, NewZeal<strong>and</strong>, Canada <strong>and</strong> the U.S. vary, certa<strong>in</strong> commonalitiesencourage comparative <strong>in</strong>quiry <strong>and</strong> a search for transferablepolicy <strong>in</strong>sights. They suggest that it would be a mistake for othergovernments to dismiss the U.S. evidence.23. A number of <strong>in</strong>digenous peoples have actively taken that step at differenttimes, from the Ktunaxa-K<strong>in</strong>basket Tribal Council <strong>in</strong> Canada to the YakamaNation <strong>in</strong> the United States. See, for example, Native Nations Institute forLeadership, Management, <strong>and</strong> Policy (2001) <strong>and</strong> Yakima Nation Review(1978).26


CornellThe overall policy implications appear to be three. First, the refusalto come to grips with <strong>Indigenous</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>s for self-determ<strong>in</strong>ationcripples the effort—prom<strong>in</strong>ent <strong>in</strong> all four countries—to overcome<strong>Indigenous</strong> poverty. The two are profoundly connected, <strong>and</strong> publicpolicy has to take this <strong>in</strong>to account.Second, implement<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Indigenous</strong> self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>and</strong>build<strong>in</strong>g self-govern<strong>in</strong>g capacities will require both <strong>in</strong>novation<strong>and</strong> a diversity of models. A one-size-fits-all approach with<strong>in</strong> anyone country—a common temptation for central governmentsconcerned with adm<strong>in</strong>istrative control <strong>and</strong> convenience—isbound to fail. 24 It will come to grief on both the varied culturaldist<strong>in</strong>ctiveness that <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples have struggled to preserve<strong>and</strong> on the social organizational diversity that each country’shistory has imposed on its <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples.Third, the best way to avoid the one-size-fits-all recipe forfailure is to let <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples decide for themselves whothe appropriate self <strong>in</strong> self-governance is <strong>and</strong> how self-govern<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>stitutions should be structured—<strong>and</strong> to accept the variety ofrelationships <strong>and</strong> governance solutions that will surely result.This is what self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation means. Furthermore, not onlyis outsider decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> this regard the antithesis ofself-determ<strong>in</strong>ation, but neither collective units nor govern<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>stitutions that are imposed by outside authorities are likely tocomm<strong>and</strong> the respect or allegiance of the peoples on whom theyare imposed—which means they will not work.The question of what will actually work ought to be of someconcern to central governments. Surely the rights of <strong>Indigenous</strong>peoples to reshape the political order they have been forced <strong>in</strong>to<strong>and</strong> to govern themselves <strong>in</strong> their own ways provides a substantial24. For discussions of a recent effort by the Canadian government to adoptjust such an approach, see Mohawk Council of Akwesasne (2002) <strong>and</strong> Cornell,et al. (2002).27


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>argument for self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation. But what the U.S. data show isthat there is an economic argument for it as well, not only fromthe po<strong>in</strong>t of view of <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples but also from the po<strong>in</strong>t ofview of central governments <strong>and</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>stream societies. They, too,have someth<strong>in</strong>g to ga<strong>in</strong>.<strong>Poverty</strong>, after all, is expensive. Its costs come <strong>in</strong> at least two forms.First, the attempt to alleviate <strong>Indigenous</strong> poverty through socialservice provision is an expensive strategy, tend<strong>in</strong>g to consist ofpalliatives <strong>in</strong>stead of cures <strong>and</strong>, therefore, to be never-end<strong>in</strong>g.Second, poverty is expensive <strong>in</strong> lost resources, trapp<strong>in</strong>g humanbe<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> dependency <strong>in</strong>stead of help<strong>in</strong>g them contribute to theirown <strong>and</strong> other societies. The U.S. data are notable <strong>in</strong> this regard,<strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that self-determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>Indigenous</strong> nations not only aremore likely to build economies that support their own peoples, but<strong>in</strong> the process also sp<strong>in</strong> off significant benefits to non-<strong>Indigenous</strong>communities through jobs, exp<strong>and</strong>ed vendor bus<strong>in</strong>ess, reducedwelfare rolls, <strong>and</strong> the like. Economically, self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation is aw<strong>in</strong>-w<strong>in</strong> proposition.If central governments reject the rights-based argument for selfdeterm<strong>in</strong>ation,one hopes their economic self-<strong>in</strong>terest will leadthem to reconsider. As my colleague Joseph Kalt <strong>and</strong> I have writtenelsewhere (Cornell <strong>and</strong> Kalt 1998), the U.S. record is clear: ifcentral governments wish to perpetuate <strong>Indigenous</strong> poverty, itsattendant ills <strong>and</strong> bitterness, <strong>and</strong> its high costs, the best way todo so is to underm<strong>in</strong>e tribal sovereignty <strong>and</strong> self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation.But if they want to overcome <strong>Indigenous</strong> poverty <strong>and</strong> all thatgoes with it, then they should support tribal sovereignty <strong>and</strong>self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation, <strong>and</strong> they should <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> help<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Indigenous</strong>peoples build the govern<strong>in</strong>g capacity to back up sovereign powerswith effective governments of their own design.28


CornellReferencesAnaya, S.J. 1996. <strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong> <strong>in</strong> International Law. NewYork: Oxford University Press.Armitage, A. 1995. Compar<strong>in</strong>g the Policy of Aborig<strong>in</strong>alAssimilation: <strong>Australia</strong>, Canada, <strong>and</strong> New Zeal<strong>and</strong>. Vancouver:University of British Columbia Press.Arthur, W.S. 2001. ‘<strong>Indigenous</strong> autonomy <strong>in</strong> <strong>Australia</strong>: Someconcepts, issues <strong>and</strong> examples.’ Discussion Paper no. 220/2001.Centre for Aborig<strong>in</strong>al Economic Policy Research, <strong>Australia</strong>nNational University.Ballara, A. 1998. Iwi: The Dynamics of Maori Tribal Organizationfrom c. 1769 to c. 1945. Well<strong>in</strong>gton: Victoria University Press.Barcham, M. 2000. ‘(De)construct<strong>in</strong>g the politics of <strong>in</strong>digeneity,’<strong>in</strong> D. Ivison, P. Patton <strong>and</strong> W. S<strong>and</strong>ers, eds., Political Theory<strong>and</strong> the Rights of <strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>. Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press. pp. 137-51.Barro, R. 1991. ‘Economic growth <strong>in</strong> a cross section of countries.’Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106: 407-43.Barsh, R.L., <strong>and</strong> R.L. Trosper. 1975. ‘Title I of the Indian <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong> <strong>and</strong> Education Assistance Act of 1975.’ AmericanIndian Law Review 3: 361-95.Beavon, D., <strong>and</strong> M. Cooke. 2001. ‘Measur<strong>in</strong>g Aborig<strong>in</strong>al wellbe<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong> four countries: An application of the UNDP’s HumanDevelopment Index to Canada, the United States, New Zeal<strong>and</strong>,<strong>and</strong> <strong>Australia</strong>.’ Presentation to the Population Association ofAmerica, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC, March 29-31.Behrendt, L. 2001. ‘<strong>Indigenous</strong> self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>in</strong> the age ofglobalization.’ Balayi: Culture, Law <strong>and</strong> Colonialism 3: 1-7.29


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>Berger, T.R. 1985. Village Journey: The Report of the AlaskaNative Review Commission. New York: Hill <strong>and</strong> Wang.Bern, J., <strong>and</strong> S. Dodds. 2000. ‘On the plurality of Interests:Aborig<strong>in</strong>al <strong>Self</strong>-Government <strong>and</strong> L<strong>and</strong> Rights,’ <strong>in</strong> D. Ivison, P.Patton <strong>and</strong> W. S<strong>and</strong>ers, eds., Political Theory <strong>and</strong> the Rights of<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. pp.163-79.Case, D., <strong>and</strong> D.A. Voluck. 2002. Alaska Natives <strong>and</strong> AmericanLaws. 2 nd edition. Fairbanks: University of Alaska Press.Ch<strong>and</strong>ler, M.J., <strong>and</strong> C. Lalonde. 1998. ‘Cultural cont<strong>in</strong>uity asa hedge aga<strong>in</strong>st suicide <strong>in</strong> Canada’s First Nations.’ Journal ofTranscultural Psychiatry 35: 191-219.Cornell, S. 1988a. The Return of the Native: American IndianPolitical Resurgence. New York: Oxford University Press.-----. 1988b. ‘The transformations of tribe: Organization <strong>and</strong>self-concept <strong>in</strong> Native American ethnicities.’ Ethnic <strong>and</strong> RacialStudies 11(1): 27-47.Cornell, S., M. Jorgensen, <strong>and</strong> J.P. Kalt. 2002. ‘The First NationsGovernance Act: Implications of research f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs from theUnited States <strong>and</strong> Canada. Report to the Office of the BritishColumbia Regional Vice-Chief, Assembly of First Nations.’Native Nations Institute for Leadership, Management, <strong>and</strong>Policy, The University of Arizona.Cornell, S., <strong>and</strong> J.P. Kalt. 1992. ‘Reload<strong>in</strong>g the dice: Improv<strong>in</strong>gthe chances for economic development on American Indianreservations,’ <strong>in</strong> S. Cornell <strong>and</strong> J.P. Kalt, eds., What Can TribesDo? Strategies <strong>and</strong> Institutions <strong>in</strong> American Indian EconomicDevelopment. Los Angeles: American Indian Studies Center,UCLA. pp. 1-59.30


Cornell-----. 1995. ‘Where does economic development really comefrom? Constitutional rule among the contemporary Sioux <strong>and</strong>Apache.’ Economic Inquiry 33: 402-26.-----. 1997a. ‘Cultural evolution <strong>and</strong> constitutional public choice:Institutional diversity <strong>and</strong> economic performance on AmericanIndian reservations,’ <strong>in</strong> J. Lott, ed., Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>and</strong> Evolution <strong>in</strong>Economics: Essays <strong>in</strong> Honor of Armen A. Alchian. London <strong>and</strong>New York: Routledge. pp. 116-42.-----. 1997b. ‘Successful economic development <strong>and</strong>heterogeneity of governmental form on American Indianreservations,’ <strong>in</strong> M.S. Gr<strong>in</strong>dle, ed., Gett<strong>in</strong>g Good Government:Capacity Build<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the Public Sectors of Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries.Cambridge, MA: Harvard Institute for InternationalDevelopment. pp. 257-96.-----. 1998. ‘Sovereignty <strong>and</strong> Nation-Build<strong>in</strong>g: The developmentchallenge <strong>in</strong> Indian country today.’ American Indian Culture <strong>and</strong>Research Journal 22(3): 187-214.-----. 2000. “Where’s the glue: Institutional <strong>and</strong> culturalfoundations of American Indian economic development.” Journalof Socio-Economics 29: 443-70.-----. 2003. ‘Alaska native self-governance <strong>and</strong> service delivery:What works?’ Jo<strong>in</strong>t Occasional Papers <strong>in</strong> Native Affairs, no.2003-1. Native Nations Institute for Leadership, Management,<strong>and</strong> Policy, <strong>and</strong> Harvard Project on American Indian EconomicDevelopment. Tucson: Udall Center for Studies <strong>in</strong> Public Policy,The University of Arizona.Cornell, S., J.P. Kalt, M. Krepps, <strong>and</strong> J. Taylor. 1998. ‘AmericanIndian gam<strong>in</strong>g policy <strong>and</strong> its socio-economic effects.’ Reportto the National Gambl<strong>in</strong>g Impact Study Commission. July.Cambridge, MA: Economics Resource Group.31


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>Deloria, V., <strong>and</strong> C.M. Lytle. 1983. American Indians, AmericanJustice. Aust<strong>in</strong>: University of Texas Press.Dodson, M., <strong>and</strong> S. Pritchard. 1998. ‘Recent developments <strong>in</strong><strong>Indigenous</strong> policy: The ab<strong>and</strong>onment of self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation?’<strong>Indigenous</strong> Law Bullet<strong>in</strong> 4(15): 4-6.Durie, M. 1998. Te Mana, Te Kāwanatanga: The Politics of Māori<strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>. Auckl<strong>and</strong>: Oxford University Press.-----. 2000. ‘Contemporary Maori development: Issues <strong>and</strong> broaddirections.’ Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper no. 7/2000. Development StudiesProgramme, University of Waikato.Egnal, M. 1996. Divergent Paths: How Culture <strong>and</strong> InstitutionsHave Shaped North American Growth. New York: OxfordUniversity Press.Esber, G.S. 1992. ‘Shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs of the Indian selfdeterm<strong>in</strong>ationpolicy,’ <strong>in</strong> G. Castile <strong>and</strong> R. Bee, eds., State <strong>and</strong>Reservation: New Perspectives on Federal Indian Policy. Tucson:University of Arizona Press. pp. 212-23.Fleras, A. 1999. ‘Politicis<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>digeneity: Ethno-politics <strong>in</strong> whitesettler dom<strong>in</strong>ions,’ <strong>in</strong> P. Havemann, ed., <strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>’ Rights<strong>in</strong> <strong>Australia</strong>, Canada, <strong>and</strong> New Zeal<strong>and</strong>. Auckl<strong>and</strong>: OxfordUniversity Press. pp. 187-234.Fleras, A., <strong>and</strong> J.L. Elliott. 1992. The ‘Nations With<strong>in</strong>’:Aborig<strong>in</strong>al-State Relations <strong>in</strong> Canada, the United States, <strong>and</strong> NewZeal<strong>and</strong>. Toronto: Oxford University Press.Fleras, A., <strong>and</strong> P. Spoonley. 1999. Recall<strong>in</strong>g Aotearoa: <strong>Indigenous</strong>Politics <strong>and</strong> Ethnic Relations <strong>in</strong> New Zeal<strong>and</strong>. Auckl<strong>and</strong>: OxfordUniversity Press.Getches, D.H. 2001. ‘Beyond Indian law: The Rehnquist court’spursuit of states’ rights, color-bl<strong>in</strong>d justice <strong>and</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>streamvalues.’ M<strong>in</strong>nesota Law Review 86(2): 267-362.32


CornellHarvard Project on American Indian Economic Development.1999. Honor<strong>in</strong>g Nations: Tribal Governance Success Stories,1999. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Project on American IndianEconomic Development, Harvard University.-----. 2000. Honor<strong>in</strong>g Nations: Tribal Governance Success Stories,2000. Cambridge: Harvard Project on American IndianEconomic Development, Harvard University.-----. 2003. Honor<strong>in</strong>g Nations: Tribal Governance Success Stories,2002. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Project on American IndianEconomic Development, Harvard University.Havemann, P. 1999. ‘Chronology two: Twentieth-century public<strong>in</strong>ternational law <strong>and</strong> <strong>Indigenous</strong> peoples,’ <strong>in</strong> P. Havemann, ed.,<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong> Rights <strong>in</strong> <strong>Australia</strong>, Canada, <strong>and</strong> New Zeal<strong>and</strong>.Auckl<strong>and</strong>: Oxford University Press. pp. 18-21.Henson, E., J.B. Taylor, S. Beane, K. Bishop, S.S. Black,K.W. Grant, M. Jorgensen, J. K<strong>in</strong>g, A.J. Lee, H. Nelson, <strong>and</strong>Y. Roubideaux. Forthcom<strong>in</strong>g. ‘Native America at the NewMillenium.’ In Harvard Project on American Indian EconomicDevelopment, American Indian Research <strong>and</strong> Grants AssessmentProject: A Report to the Ford Foundation.Humpage, L.V. 2002. ‘Clos<strong>in</strong>g the gaps? The politics ofMaori affairs policy.’ Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, MasseyUniversity.Hunter, B. 1999. ‘Three nations, not one: <strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>and</strong> other<strong>Australia</strong>n poverty.’ Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper No. 1/1999. Centre forAborig<strong>in</strong>al Economic Policy Research, <strong>Australia</strong>n NationalUniversity.<strong>Indigenous</strong> Constitutional Convention Secretariat. c. 1999.‘<strong>Indigenous</strong> Constitutional Strategy, Northern Territory.’33


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong><strong>Indigenous</strong> Constitutional Convention Secretariat, Casuar<strong>in</strong>a,Northern Territory, <strong>Australia</strong>.Ivison, D. 2002. Postcolonial Liberalism. Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press.-----. 2003. ‘The logic of Aborig<strong>in</strong>al rights.’ Ethnicities 3(3): 321-44.Ivison, D., P. Patton <strong>and</strong> W. S<strong>and</strong>ers, eds. 2000. Political Theory<strong>and</strong> the Rights of <strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>. Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press.Jorgensen, M. 1997. ‘Govern<strong>in</strong>g Government.’ Unpublishedmanuscript, John F. Kennedy School of Government, HarvardUniversity.-----. 2000a. ‘Br<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g the background forward: Evidence fromIndian Country on the social <strong>and</strong> cultural determ<strong>in</strong>ants ofeconomic development.’ Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, John F.Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University.-----. 2000b. ‘History’s lesson for HUD <strong>and</strong> tribes.’ Unpublishedmanuscript, John F. Kennedy School of Government, HarvardUniversity.-----, editor. Forthcom<strong>in</strong>g. Resources for Nation Build<strong>in</strong>g:Governance, Development, <strong>and</strong> the Future of American IndianNations. Tucson: University of Arizona Press.Jorgensen, M., R. Akee, C. Goodswimmer, <strong>and</strong> S.C. Ra<strong>in</strong>ie.Forthcom<strong>in</strong>g. ‘Underst<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g First Nations’ developmentsuccess: Cross-site analysis of four First Nations <strong>in</strong> Treaty 8,Alberta.’ Native Nations Institute for Leadership, Management,<strong>and</strong> Policy, The University of Arizona.34


CornellJorgensen, M., <strong>and</strong> J. Taylor. 2000. ‘Patterns of Indian enterprisesuccess: A statistical analysis of tribal <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual Indianenterprise performance.’ Report to the National Congressof American Indians. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Project onAmerican Indian Economic Development, John F. KennedySchool of Government, Harvard University.Knack, S., <strong>and</strong> P. Keefer. 1995. ‘Institutions <strong>and</strong> economicperformance: Cross-country tests us<strong>in</strong>g alternative <strong>in</strong>stitutionalmeasures.’ Economics <strong>and</strong> Politics 7(3): 207-27.Krepps, M.B. 1992. ‘Can Tribes Manage their own Resources?The 638 Program <strong>and</strong> American Indian Forestry,’ <strong>in</strong> WhatCan Tribes Do? Strategies <strong>and</strong> Institutions <strong>in</strong> American IndianEconomic Development, ed. S. Cornell <strong>and</strong> J. P. Kalt. Los Angeles:American Indian Studies Center, UCLA. pp. 179-203.Krepps, M.B., <strong>and</strong> R.E. Caves. 1994. ‘Bureaucrats <strong>and</strong> Indians:Pr<strong>in</strong>cipal-agent relations <strong>and</strong> efficient management of tribalforest resources.’ Journal of Economic Behavior <strong>and</strong> Organization24(2): 133-51.La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, <strong>and</strong> R.W. Vishney.1997. ‘Legal determ<strong>in</strong>ants of external f<strong>in</strong>ance.’ Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance52(3): 1131-50.-----. 1998. ‘Law <strong>and</strong> F<strong>in</strong>ance.’ Journal of Political Economy 106(December): 1113-55.-----. 1999. ‘The quality of government.’ Journal of Law,Economics <strong>and</strong> Organization 15 (April): 222-79.Lipset, S.M. 1963. Political Man: The Social Bases of Politics. NewYork: Anchor.Loomis, T. 2000. ‘Government’s role <strong>in</strong> Maori development:Chart<strong>in</strong>g a new direction?’ Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper no. 6/2000.Development Studies Programme, University of Waikato.35


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>Maaka, R., <strong>and</strong> A. Fleras. 2000. ‘Engag<strong>in</strong>g with Indigeneity:T<strong>in</strong>o rangatiratanga <strong>in</strong> Aotearoa,’ <strong>in</strong> D. Ivison, P. Patton <strong>and</strong> W.S<strong>and</strong>ers, eds., Political Theory <strong>and</strong> the Rights of <strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. pp. 89-109.McNeil, K. 1998. Def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Aborig<strong>in</strong>al Title <strong>in</strong> the 90’s: Has theSupreme Court F<strong>in</strong>ally Got it Right? Toronto: Robarts Centre forCanadian Studies, York University.Mart<strong>in</strong>, D.F. 2001. ‘Is welfare dependency “welfare poison’”? Anassessment of Noel Pearson’s proposals for Aborig<strong>in</strong>al welfarereform.’ Discussion Paper no. 213/2001. Centre for Aborig<strong>in</strong>alEconomic Policy Research, <strong>Australia</strong>n National University.Mohawk Council of Akwesasne. 2002. Nation Build<strong>in</strong>g Process:Sett<strong>in</strong>g Our Path for the Future. Cornwall, Ontario: MohawkCouncil of Akwesasne.Moore, M.A., H. Forbes, <strong>and</strong> L. Henderson. 1990. ‘Theprovision of primary health care services under b<strong>and</strong> control:The Montreal Lake case.’ Native Studies Review 6(1): 153-64.Moran, A. 2002. ‘As <strong>Australia</strong> decolonizes: <strong>in</strong>digeniz<strong>in</strong>g settlernationalism <strong>and</strong> the challenges of settler/<strong>Indigenous</strong> relations.’Ethnic <strong>and</strong> Racial Studies 25(2): 1013-1042.Morse, B.W. 1998. ‘Two steps forward <strong>and</strong> one step back:The frustrat<strong>in</strong>g pace of build<strong>in</strong>g a new Aborig<strong>in</strong>al-Crownrelationship <strong>in</strong> Canada,’ <strong>in</strong> C.P. Cohen, ed., The Human Rights of<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>. Ardsley, New York: Transnational Publishers.pp. 303-56.Nagel, J. 1996. American Indian Ethnic Renewal: Red Power<strong>and</strong> the Resurgence of Identity <strong>and</strong> Culture. New York: OxfordUniversity Press.36


CornellNative Nations Institute for Leadership, Management, <strong>and</strong>Policy. 2001. ‘Ktunaxa/K<strong>in</strong>basket Tribal Council: F<strong>in</strong>al reporton governmental organization <strong>and</strong> nation build<strong>in</strong>g.’ Udall Centerfor Studies <strong>in</strong> Public Policy, The University of Arizona, Tucson.Nettheim, G., G.D. Meyers, <strong>and</strong> D. Craig. 2002. <strong>Indigenous</strong><strong>Peoples</strong> <strong>and</strong> Governance Structures: A Comparative Analysis ofL<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Resource Management Rights. Canberra: Aborig<strong>in</strong>alStudies Press, <strong>Australia</strong>n Institute of Aborig<strong>in</strong>al <strong>and</strong> TorresStrait Isl<strong>and</strong>er Studies.North, D.C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change <strong>and</strong> EconomicPerformance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Oberschall, A. 1990. ‘Incentives, governance, <strong>and</strong> development <strong>in</strong>Ch<strong>in</strong>ese collective agriculture,’ <strong>in</strong> M. Hechter, K.D. Opp, <strong>and</strong> R.Wippler, eds., Social Institutions: Their Emergence, Ma<strong>in</strong>tenance<strong>and</strong> Effects. New York: Ald<strong>in</strong>e de Gruyter. pp. 265-89.Ostrom, E. 1992. Craft<strong>in</strong>g Institutions for <strong>Self</strong>-Govern<strong>in</strong>g IrrigationSystems. San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies.Perry, R.J. 1996. From Time Immemorial: <strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong> <strong>and</strong>State Systems. Aust<strong>in</strong>: University of Texas Press.Pocock, J.G.A. 2000. ‘Waitangi as mystery of state:Consequences of the ascription of federative capacity to theMaori,’ <strong>in</strong> D. Ivison, P. Patton <strong>and</strong> W. S<strong>and</strong>ers, eds., PoliticalTheory <strong>and</strong> the Rights of <strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>. Cambridge:Cambridge University Press. pp. 25-35.Price, R.T. 2001. ‘New Zeal<strong>and</strong>’s <strong>in</strong>terim treaty settlements <strong>and</strong>arrangements—build<strong>in</strong>g blocks of certa<strong>in</strong>ty,’ <strong>in</strong> British ColumbiaTreaty Commission, Speak<strong>in</strong>g Truth to Power: A Treaty Forum.Law Commission of Canada. pp. 135-63.37


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>Royal Commission on Aborig<strong>in</strong>al <strong>Peoples</strong>. 1996. People toPeople, Nation to Nation: Highlights from the Report of the RoyalCommission on Aborig<strong>in</strong>al <strong>Peoples</strong>. Ottawa: M<strong>in</strong>ister of Supply<strong>and</strong> Services, Canada.Salée, D. 1995. ‘Identities <strong>in</strong> conflict: the Aborig<strong>in</strong>al question<strong>and</strong> the politics of recognition <strong>in</strong> Quebec.’ Ethnic <strong>and</strong> RacialStudies 18(2): 277-314.S<strong>and</strong>ers, W. 2002. ‘Towards an <strong>Indigenous</strong> order of <strong>Australia</strong>ngovernment: Reth<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation as <strong>Indigenous</strong> affairspolicy.’ Discussion Paper No. 230/2002. Centre for Aborig<strong>in</strong>alEconomic Policy Research, <strong>Australia</strong>n National University.Scott, C.H. 1993. ‘Custom, tradition, <strong>and</strong> the politics of culture:Aborig<strong>in</strong>al self-government <strong>in</strong> Canada,’ <strong>in</strong> N. Dyck <strong>and</strong> J.B.Waldram, eds., Anthropology, Public Policy <strong>and</strong> Native <strong>Peoples</strong> <strong>in</strong>Canada. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press. pp. 311-33.Smith, D. 1993. The Seventh Fire: The Struggle for Aborig<strong>in</strong>alGovernment. Toronto: Key Porter Books.Smith, D.E. 2002. ‘Jurisdictional devolution: Towards aneffective model for <strong>Indigenous</strong> community self-determ<strong>in</strong>ation.’Discussion Paper no. 233/2002. Centre for Aborig<strong>in</strong>alEconomic Policy Research, <strong>Australia</strong>n National University.Tully, J. 2000. ‘The struggles of <strong>Indigenous</strong> people for <strong>and</strong> offreedom,’ <strong>in</strong> D. Ivison, P. Patton <strong>and</strong> W. S<strong>and</strong>ers, Political Theory<strong>and</strong> the Rights of <strong>Indigenous</strong> People. Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press. pp. 36-59.United Nations Development Programme. 2003. HumanDevelopment Report 2002: Deepen<strong>in</strong>g Democracy <strong>in</strong> a FragmentedWorld. New York: United Nations Development Programme.38


CornellWakel<strong>in</strong>g, S., M. Jorgensen, S. Michaelson, <strong>and</strong> M. Begay.2001. Polic<strong>in</strong>g on American Indian Reservations: A Report to theNational Institute of Justice. Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC: National Instituteof Justice, United States Department of Justice.Walker, R. 1990. Ka Whawhai Tonu Matou: Struggle WithoutEnd. Auckl<strong>and</strong>: Pengu<strong>in</strong>.Wilk<strong>in</strong>s, D. 2002. American Indian Politics <strong>and</strong> the AmericanPolitical System. Lanham, MD: Rowman <strong>and</strong> Littlefield.Yakima Nation Review. 1978. ‘1855 Yakima Treaty chronicles.’Yakima Nation Review 9(3), June 23.39


<strong>Indigenous</strong> <strong>Peoples</strong>, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-<strong>Determ<strong>in</strong>ation</strong>40


Jo<strong>in</strong>t Occasional Papers on Native AffairsThe papers <strong>in</strong> this series are issued jo<strong>in</strong>tly by the Native Nations Institutefor Leadership, Management, <strong>and</strong> Policy (NNI) at the University ofArizona, <strong>and</strong> the Harvard Project on American Indian Economic Development(Harvard Project) at Harvard University. The views expressed <strong>in</strong> this reportare those of the author(s) <strong>and</strong> do not necessarily reflect those of NNI, theHarvard Project, their respective host centers <strong>and</strong> universities, or past <strong>and</strong> presentsponsors. For further <strong>in</strong>formation about the Native Nations Institute, contacthttp://nni.arizona.edu or 520-626-0664. For further <strong>in</strong>formation about theHarvard Project contact http://www.ksg.harvard.edu/hpaied or 617-495-1480.Series EditorsStephen Cornell, University of ArizonaMiriam Jorgensen, University of Arizona & Harvard UniversityJoseph P. Kalt, Harvard UniversityManag<strong>in</strong>g EditorEmily McGovern, University of ArizonaUdall Center PublicationsRobert Merideth, editor <strong>in</strong> chiefEmily McGovern, editorial associateRenee La Roi, graphic designer


N AT I V E NAT I O N S IN S T I T U T Efor Leadership, Management, <strong>and</strong> PolicyUdall Center for Studies <strong>in</strong> Public PolicyUniversity of Arizonanni.arizona.eduwww.ksg.harvard.edu/hpaied

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!