12.07.2015 Views

Participative analysis of coffee supply chain in Lao PDR - LAD - nafri

Participative analysis of coffee supply chain in Lao PDR - LAD - nafri

Participative analysis of coffee supply chain in Lao PDR - LAD - nafri

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Groupe de Travail Café (GTC)<strong>Participative</strong> <strong>analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong><strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong>Gal<strong>in</strong>do J 1 ., Sallée B 2 .With the participation <strong>of</strong>Manivong P. 3 , Mahavong P. 4 , David A. 5 , Homevongsa V. 3 , Mongpadith S. 3 , Guitet C. 6November 20071 PAB-PCADR project., Pakse-Champasak, <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong>. juliangal<strong>in</strong>do@yahoo.fr2 LCG-Cirad, PAB-PCADR project. Pakse-Champasak, <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong>. sallee@cirad.fr3 National University <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s. Faculty <strong>of</strong> Agriculture <strong>of</strong> Nabong, <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong>.4 PAB-PCADR project. Pakse-Champasak, <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong>.5 INSFA, Agrocampus Rennes, PEIG project.6 English Pr<strong>of</strong>essor, Pakse-Champasak, <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong><strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 2


8. CONCLUSIONS ON LAO COFFEE SECTOR ANALYSIS ......................................................................................... 769. BIBLIOGRAPHY / REFERENCES......................................................................................................................... 799.1. BIBLIOGRAPHY ............................................................................................................................................. 799.2. WEBSITES..................................................................................................................................................... 79ANNEXES ..................................................................................................................................................................... 80Index <strong>of</strong> figuresFigure 1: Evolution <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces and production <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s (1976-2005) ..................................................... 22Figure 2: <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exports (MT) (1995 – 2007) ................................................................................................... 24Figure 3: Share <strong>of</strong> robusta <strong>in</strong> world c<strong>of</strong>fee production (1969-2003) ................................................................... 25Figure 4: Importance <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> households’ annual <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau................................... 29Figure 5: General scheme <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>in</strong> 2007 (for export c<strong>of</strong>fee)............................................ 32Figure 6: Robusta yields <strong>in</strong> 2007 (households’ distribution ranges) .................................................................. 33Figure 7: Arabica yields <strong>in</strong> 2007 (households’ distribution ranges)................................................................... 35Figure 8: Percentage <strong>of</strong> external labor dur<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee harvest (<strong>in</strong> % <strong>of</strong> households <strong>in</strong>terviewed) .................. 45Figure 9: C<strong>of</strong>fee harvest workforce demand (number <strong>of</strong> day-worker / ha)...................................................... 45Figure 10: Harvest workforce productivity (average weight <strong>of</strong> cherries harvested / day-worker)............... 46Figure 11: Comparison between family and external waged labor (Kg <strong>of</strong> cherries harvested / day)........... 46Figure 12: Scheme <strong>of</strong> local-style roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>............................................................................. 57Figure 13: Scheme <strong>of</strong> “European-style” roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> ................................................................ 58Figure 14: Simplified scheme <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fees <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> ............................................................................ 58Figure 15: Scheme <strong>of</strong> natural robusta circuit......................................................................................................... 66Figure 16: Scheme <strong>of</strong> washed arabica circuit ........................................................................................................ 66Figure 17: Scheme <strong>of</strong> niche markets circuit ........................................................................................................... 69Figure 18: Summary <strong>of</strong> farmers’ cash loans modalities....................................................................................... 70Figure 19: Ratio between cash loans and total c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong>come (sample <strong>of</strong> 200 households) ............................ 71Figure 20 : <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee circuits value <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong>.............................................................................................. 74Index <strong>of</strong> tablesTable 1: Ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>’s <strong>analysis</strong> steps.......................................................................................................... 17Table 2: Ma<strong>in</strong> study’s data collect tools ................................................................................................................. 18Table 3: Total c<strong>of</strong>fee area and production by region <strong>in</strong> 2004-2005..................................................................... 20Table 4: Other productive activities <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau............................................................................... 21Table 5: Evolution <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces and species share <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau.............................................. 22Table 6: Boloven Plateau c<strong>of</strong>fee productive situation <strong>in</strong> 2007............................................................................. 23Table 7: C<strong>of</strong>fee area and exports <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> robusta produc<strong>in</strong>g countries............................................................24Table 8: <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exports (MT) by import<strong>in</strong>g country (2002 – 2006) .............................................................. 26Table 9: Value <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Exports 2004-2005 (USD) .................................................................................... 29Table 10: C<strong>of</strong>fee consumption (<strong>in</strong> Kg/capita/year) <strong>in</strong> some import<strong>in</strong>g and export<strong>in</strong>g countries................... 30Table 11: Characterization <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee domestic market ......................................................................................... 30Table 12: Characteristics <strong>of</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fea canephora cropp<strong>in</strong>g system <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau ................................... 33Table 13: Characteristics <strong>of</strong> arabica cropp<strong>in</strong>g system <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau.................................................. 34Table 14: Robusta c<strong>of</strong>fee dry-process <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau............................................................................. 36Table 15: Wet process system <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau.......................................................................................... 37Table 16: Ma<strong>in</strong> criteria lead<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>dividual farmersʹ typology........................................................................ 39Table 17: Characterization <strong>of</strong> farmersʹ typology groups ..................................................................................... 40Table 18: C<strong>of</strong>fee production limit<strong>in</strong>g factors......................................................................................................... 44Table 19: Forecast <strong>of</strong> arabica production <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau <strong>in</strong> 2009 and 2012......................................... 47Table 20: Estimation <strong>of</strong> global workforce needs for arabica harvest <strong>in</strong> 2009 and 2012 ................................... 47Table 21: Exportersʹ typology.................................................................................................................................. 51<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 4


Table 22: C<strong>of</strong>fee export procedures and costs <strong>in</strong> 1999 and 2006......................................................................... 52Table 23: Ma<strong>in</strong> steps <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee export lots preparation ............................................................................. 53Table 24: Role <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector secondary actors ......................................................................................... 55Table 25: Prices paid by roast<strong>in</strong>g companies <strong>in</strong> 2007 ........................................................................................... 59Table 26: Roast<strong>in</strong>g technical characteristics........................................................................................................... 60Table 27: Roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee productsʹ differentiation criteria.................................................................................. 60Table 28: <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fees cup tast<strong>in</strong>g results................................................................................................................ 61Table 29: Example <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee products’ range <strong>in</strong> Vientiane m<strong>in</strong>i-marts for 3 major brands ............................ 61Table 30: Ranges <strong>of</strong> sell<strong>in</strong>g prices for different categories <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee product <strong>in</strong> the domestic market .......... 62Table 31: Domestic market: buyers and consumers typology ............................................................................ 62Table 32: Characterization <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee consumption <strong>in</strong> domestic market.............................................................63Table 33: Domestic market: places <strong>of</strong> purchas<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee..................................................................................... 64Table 34: Functional <strong>analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>stream export circuit................................................................................ 67Table 35: Ma<strong>in</strong>stream export circuit actors’ strategies......................................................................................... 68Table 36: Percentage <strong>of</strong> households hav<strong>in</strong>g made pre-harvest loans accord<strong>in</strong>g to their social status.......... 69Table 37: Type <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sold by farmers dur<strong>in</strong>g 2006/2007 campaign..............................................................71Table 38: First c<strong>of</strong>fee buyers .................................................................................................................................... 72Table 39: Ma<strong>in</strong> quality criteria and controll<strong>in</strong>g methods dur<strong>in</strong>g first c<strong>of</strong>fee sell<strong>in</strong>g ....................................... 72Table 40: Prices paid to producers dur<strong>in</strong>g 2006/2007 campaign ........................................................................ 72Table 41: Summary <strong>of</strong> strengths, weaknesses, opportunities and threats <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector (SWOT<strong>analysis</strong>)...................................................................................................................................................................... 77Table 42: Example <strong>of</strong> SWOT <strong>analysis</strong> output <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> strategies for c<strong>of</strong>fee sector...................................... 78AnnexesAnnex 1: Ma<strong>in</strong> characteristics <strong>of</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fea arabica and C<strong>of</strong>fea canephora species .................................................... 80Annex 2: Ma<strong>in</strong> caracteristics <strong>of</strong> arabica and robusta c<strong>of</strong>fees............................................................................... 80Annex 3: C<strong>of</strong>fee process<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s from beans to commercial green c<strong>of</strong>fee.................................................. 81Annex 4: International c<strong>of</strong>fee prices (1975 – 2007) ............................................................................................... 81Annex 5: Farmers’ survey village list..................................................................................................................... 82Annex 6: <strong>Lao</strong> export c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> scheme ................................................................................................ 83Annex 7: Price structure for natural robusta <strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong>stream export circuit................................................ 84Annex 8: Price structure for washed arabica <strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong>stream export circuit ............................................... 85Annex 9: Price structure for washed arabica <strong>in</strong> niche market circuit (example <strong>of</strong> farmers’ export groups) 86<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 5


Acronyms and abbreviationsAFD: Agence Française de Développement (French Development Agency)AGPC: Association de Groupements de Producteurs de Café du Plateau des Boloven (Boloven PlateauC<strong>of</strong>fee Producers’ Groups Association)CIRAD: Centre de Coopération Internationale Agronomique pour le DéveloppementCNCL: Conseil National du Café <strong>Lao</strong> (<strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee National Council)CREC: Centre de Recherche et d’Expérimentations sur le Café (C<strong>of</strong>fee Research and ExperimentationCentre)FAQ: Fare Average QualityGTC: Groupe de Travail Café (C<strong>of</strong>fee Work<strong>in</strong>g Group)ICO: International C<strong>of</strong>fee OrganizationINSFA: Institut National Supérieur des Sciences de l’Agro-alimentaire, National Superior Institute <strong>of</strong>Agri-bus<strong>in</strong>ess SciencesJICA: Japanese International Cooperation AgencyJCFC: Jhai C<strong>of</strong>fee Farmer CooperativeLCA: <strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee AssociationLMC: <strong>Lao</strong> Mounta<strong>in</strong> C<strong>of</strong>feeLUADP: <strong>Lao</strong> Upland Agricultural Development ProjectMAF: M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and ForestryMIC: M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> Industry and CommercePAB: Po<strong>in</strong>t d’Application des Boloven du PCADR (PCADR implementation po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> the Boloven)PCADR: Programme de Capitalisation pour l’Appui à la politique de Développement Rural (Program <strong>of</strong>capitalization <strong>in</strong> support to rural development strategies and policies)<strong>PDR</strong>PB: Projet de Développement Rural du Plateau des Boloven (Boloven Plateau Rural DevelopmentProject)PEIG: Projet d’Etablissement des Indications Géographiques au <strong>Lao</strong>s (Support program on theestablishment <strong>of</strong> Geographical Indications <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s)UC-PCADR: Unité Centrale du PCADR (PCADR’s Central Unit)<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 6


Executive summaryQuick overview <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector todayHistoryThe first c<strong>of</strong>fee plantations <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s were set around 1920 by French settlers <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau. They<strong>in</strong>troduced arabica trees from Bourbon and Typica varieties. From 1950 onwards, different externalfactors: war, frost episodes and leaf rust attacks provoked a disorganization <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s andthe progressive replacement <strong>of</strong> arabica plantations with newly <strong>in</strong>troduced resistant species, ma<strong>in</strong>ly C<strong>of</strong>feacanephora (robusta).The period go<strong>in</strong>g from 1975 to 1990 was characterized by the sett<strong>in</strong>g up <strong>of</strong> a State-controlled c<strong>of</strong>fee sector.Collection; trad<strong>in</strong>g, export<strong>in</strong>g as well as prices’ policies were government-controlled. This productiondirectedpolicy triggered a drop <strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee quality as farmers took less care <strong>of</strong> their plantations andsimplified harvest and post-harvest practices (farmers focused on volumes to the detriment <strong>of</strong> quality).In the 90’s, the convergence <strong>of</strong> different factors such as a new economic conjuncture, the rise <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeprices <strong>in</strong> 1994 and the devaluation <strong>of</strong> national currency triggered a strong development <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exportsector. Concurrently, national authorities through the support <strong>of</strong> development projects started to promotearabica production by <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g the high-productive dwarf variety Catimor. Until then, C. canephorarepresented more than 95% <strong>of</strong> total c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces. S<strong>in</strong>ce 1995, the share <strong>of</strong> arabica has been steadily<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g to such extent it now stands for 13 % <strong>of</strong> total c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces.Production areaEvolution <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces and species share <strong>in</strong> the Boloven PlateauYear Total surface (ha) Robusta % Arabica %1990 17,066 > 99 % Residual Typica1999 25,000 98,5 % 1,5 %2007 45,000 87 % 13 %Today, more than 99% <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee is produced <strong>in</strong> Southern <strong>Lao</strong>s, and more specifically <strong>in</strong> the BolovenPlateau. Located at a latitude <strong>of</strong> 15° N, with altitudes rang<strong>in</strong>g from 400 to 1400 m which attenuates thegreat variability <strong>of</strong> monsoons and ensures regular dry-season ra<strong>in</strong>falls (important for c<strong>of</strong>fee flower<strong>in</strong>g andfirst stages <strong>of</strong> cherries development), the Boloven Plateau is a very suitable place for C<strong>of</strong>fea arabicagrow<strong>in</strong>g. Besides, the relatively cool climate (between November and February) allows an adequatevegetative development <strong>in</strong> the same time it confers organoleptic qualities to f<strong>in</strong>al product.Surpris<strong>in</strong>gly, the Boloven is not the most suitable place for the grow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fea canephora (native <strong>of</strong> Wets-African lowland ra<strong>in</strong>-forests). In high altitudes, low temperatures lead to flower abortions; <strong>in</strong> lowaltitudes robusta trees suffer from the lack <strong>of</strong> water (lead<strong>in</strong>g to defoliations). However, thanks to itsresistance and strong adaptation capacity, C. canephora managed to adapt to the local environment.Today, c<strong>of</strong>fee is the ma<strong>in</strong> crop for a large majority <strong>of</strong> families <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau. Below 800-900 mfarmers mostly grow robusta; above 800-900 m farmers have started to plant dwarf arabica trees <strong>in</strong> newareas or <strong>in</strong>side old robusta plantations. Besides c<strong>of</strong>fee, farmers develop other activities ma<strong>in</strong>ly l<strong>in</strong>ked toagriculture (ra<strong>in</strong> fed rice, vegetables, fruit trees, etc.) and livestock breed<strong>in</strong>g.Robustaarea(ha)Estimatedproduction(MT <strong>of</strong> greenc<strong>of</strong>fee)Boloven Plateau c<strong>of</strong>fee productive situation <strong>in</strong> 2007Arabica area(ha)Estimatedproduction(MT <strong>of</strong> greenc<strong>of</strong>fee)Youngunproductivearabica surfaces(ha)Nurseries(number <strong>of</strong>plants)Potential newarabica area (ha)39,000 15,500 6,000 3,000 6,000 15’000,000 3,300Sources: Extrapolation from PAB figures and 2007 producers’ survey consider<strong>in</strong>g a total number <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee produc<strong>in</strong>g villages <strong>in</strong> theBoloven Plateau <strong>of</strong> 125 for a total number <strong>of</strong> 15,300 households.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 7


Relations with <strong>in</strong>ternational economy (c<strong>of</strong>fee export sector)With an annual output <strong>of</strong> 10,000 to 20,000 MT <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee (80% <strong>of</strong> which is robusta), <strong>Lao</strong>s is a verysmall producer on the world scale (less than 0.2% <strong>of</strong> world c<strong>of</strong>fee production). In comparison, Vietnamexports around 800,000 MT/year 7 , Indonesia 300,000 MT, Uganda 130,000 MT, Cameroon 45,000 MT andThailand 30,000 MT.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exports (MT) (2000 – 2007)2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 June-07Robusta 13,800 13,695 12,340 12,401 20,752 6,077 5,487 14,482Arabica 200 350 603 294 2,505 2,255 1,277 1,885Total 14,000 14,045 13,330 12,821 23,656 8,578 6,877 16,367Source: <strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee AssociationUnlike many traditional robusta export<strong>in</strong>g countries (especially <strong>in</strong> Africa) which exports have decreased,<strong>Lao</strong> exports have rema<strong>in</strong>ed steady <strong>in</strong> the past ten years (except for seasonal drops due to climate eventslike <strong>in</strong> 2005 and 2006). The ma<strong>in</strong> reasons are an advantageous currency rate policy (devaluation <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>Kip) as well as an <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g demand for low-price c<strong>of</strong>fee with low quality standards for the needs <strong>of</strong> anexpand<strong>in</strong>g down-market c<strong>of</strong>fee segment (that generally uses robusta c<strong>of</strong>fee).<strong>Lao</strong> robusta turns out to be very attractive for <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee buyers as they can buy it at a quite lowprice (there are not quality standards and there is a price penalty for <strong>Lao</strong> orig<strong>in</strong>) and it has certa<strong>in</strong>organoleptic qualities (<strong>Lao</strong> robusta is s<strong>of</strong>t and balanced which makes it <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> roasted c<strong>of</strong>feeblends).The prices <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee depend entirely on the <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee prices (small production, absence fromall <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee bodies, little power <strong>of</strong> negotiation, etc.). In practice, the price <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> robusta is fixedaccord<strong>in</strong>g to the <strong>in</strong>ternational price fixed <strong>in</strong> London. In the past three years this price was around 1,600USD/MT. On the other hand, the price <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> arabica is decided accord<strong>in</strong>g to the price <strong>of</strong> “other arabicamilds” <strong>in</strong> the New York market. Currently this price is around 2,600 USD/MT.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee is ma<strong>in</strong>ly exported to European countries like Poland, Germany, Belgium and Switzerland.Exports to Vietnam have also considerably <strong>in</strong>creased but there is very few <strong>in</strong>formation about this issue(re-export? local consumption?). Ma<strong>in</strong> buyers <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee are <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee traders represented bytheir local agents. In import<strong>in</strong>g countries, <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee is ma<strong>in</strong>ly used for c<strong>of</strong>fee blends or <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>feemak<strong>in</strong>g without any orig<strong>in</strong> recognition.Another remarkable fact is that <strong>in</strong> spite <strong>of</strong> the alleged uniqueness (<strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> taste) and the great demand<strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> robusta, c<strong>of</strong>fee exports still suffer from a price penalty <strong>of</strong> around 100-150 USD/MT accord<strong>in</strong>g to the<strong>in</strong>ternational price (London). It seems that <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee has not managed to get rid <strong>of</strong> a certa<strong>in</strong> badreputation <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational quality standards and the reliability <strong>of</strong> its operators.As <strong>Lao</strong>s is a landlocked country, c<strong>of</strong>fee must be exported through a neighbor country which is generallyThailand (through Vangtao/Chong Mek check po<strong>in</strong>t). The transport from Chong Mek to the port(Bangkok) is generally carried out by a Thai shipp<strong>in</strong>g company which engenders high transportationcosts.Relations with national economyC<strong>of</strong>fee is a major agricultural export commodity (it represented 16% <strong>of</strong> total agricultural exports <strong>in</strong>2004/2005). At regional level (Boloven Plateau), c<strong>of</strong>fee is a first-order crop for around 15,000 households.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to our estimations, it represents 30 to 40% <strong>of</strong> total surface and rema<strong>in</strong>s by far the ma<strong>in</strong> crop <strong>in</strong>zones above 900 m <strong>of</strong> altitude. Besides, it is by far the ma<strong>in</strong> source <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come for more than 80% <strong>of</strong> thehouseholds <strong>in</strong> this area.7 All figures quoted <strong>in</strong>clude robusta and arabica. However, all countries named are ma<strong>in</strong>ly robusta producers.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 8


It also generates employment and economic activities <strong>in</strong>ternally through the domestic market <strong>of</strong> roastedc<strong>of</strong>fee. In the past years, this market has spectacularly developed boosted by a bunch <strong>of</strong> very dynamiccompanies that have managed to develop a wide range <strong>of</strong> products and to promote new consumptionbehaviors.In spite <strong>of</strong> its economic importance, there is a quite weak implication <strong>of</strong> national authorities and a verylow level <strong>of</strong> organization among ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee actors (except for exporters).Ma<strong>in</strong> actors and activities <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>Ma<strong>in</strong> actors <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> are (i) <strong>in</strong>dividual producers, farmers’ groups and private <strong>in</strong>vestors(production level), (ii) village buyers and wholesalers (trad<strong>in</strong>g), (iii) exporters and local importer agents(export), (iv) roast<strong>in</strong>g companies and retailers (domestic market) and (v) consumers. Some importantsecondary actors are government and government-l<strong>in</strong>ked bodies, development projects, banks and other<strong>in</strong>formal credit services providers.General scheme <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>in</strong> 2007 (for export c<strong>of</strong>fee)Private<strong>in</strong>vestors’plantationsIndividual farmersVillage middle-buyersFarmers’cooperativesDistrict-town wholesalersPlanter-exporters and wholesaler-exportersC<strong>of</strong>fee flowsCash flowsImporters’ local agentsInternational c<strong>of</strong>fee traders/ Importers / RoastersC<strong>of</strong>fee productionCropp<strong>in</strong>g and process<strong>in</strong>g systemsMa<strong>in</strong> factors hav<strong>in</strong>g affected c<strong>of</strong>fee production <strong>in</strong> the past 10 years are: <strong>in</strong> the one hand the <strong>in</strong>troductionand extension <strong>of</strong> dwarf-variety arabica cropp<strong>in</strong>g system by <strong>in</strong>dividual farmers and private <strong>in</strong>vestors withthe progressive adoption <strong>of</strong> the wet-method process and on the other hand the entry <strong>of</strong> small amounts <strong>of</strong><strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee (arabica) produced by farmers’ groups <strong>in</strong>to high quality niche markets.There are three ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee cropp<strong>in</strong>g systems <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau:• The C.canephora cropp<strong>in</strong>g system, which is the most widespread. It is a low <strong>in</strong>tensive system,without chemical <strong>in</strong>put, adapted to divagation system <strong>of</strong> cattle. It is also an economically non risky system(very low level <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts <strong>of</strong> workforce and capital).• The former arabica Typica cropp<strong>in</strong>g system, technically similar to the canephora cropp<strong>in</strong>g systemand that is progressively be<strong>in</strong>g abandoned (except for farmer groups that exports arabica Typica to nichemarkets).• The arabica dwarf-variety (Catimor) cropp<strong>in</strong>g system that has been well adopted by producers andis rapidly spread<strong>in</strong>g. Most plantations are still young. It is an <strong>in</strong>tensive system very high-demand<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong>labor and fertilization.Regard<strong>in</strong>g post-harvest techniques, there are two ma<strong>in</strong> ways <strong>of</strong> process<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee• Almost all robusta c<strong>of</strong>fee is processed with the dry-method, that is to say that cherries are directlysun-dried and green c<strong>of</strong>fee is obta<strong>in</strong>ed by shell<strong>in</strong>g dried-cherries. With this system very little care is paid<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 9


dur<strong>in</strong>g harvest and port-harvest stages: farmers carry out the drip-pick<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> cherries, many <strong>of</strong> them drycherries on the bare ground, etc. The quality control system set by buyers is light, subjective andengenders penalties to producers. Producers sell both dried-cherries and unsorted green c<strong>of</strong>fee.• Arabica post-harvest process is the wet-method; cherries are pulped, fermented, washed and dried(they obta<strong>in</strong> dried parchment c<strong>of</strong>fee). This system requires different mach<strong>in</strong>es and <strong>in</strong>frastructures (called“wet-mills”) <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g pulp<strong>in</strong>g mach<strong>in</strong>es, fermentation tanks, wash<strong>in</strong>g canals, etc. Moreover, it demandsa good care <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee beans dur<strong>in</strong>g harvest and post-harvest stages. This system has been recently adoptedby producers without any problems <strong>of</strong> adaptation. Today, its ma<strong>in</strong> limit<strong>in</strong>g factor is farmers’ process<strong>in</strong>gcapacity (f<strong>in</strong>ancial capability to build either <strong>in</strong>dividual or collective wet-mills).C<strong>of</strong>fee production actorsIndividual farmers are the ma<strong>in</strong> actors <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee primary production (they cultivate more than 40,000 ha)and we can estimate that c<strong>of</strong>fee provides livelihood to around 15,000 households <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau.Based on a comprehensive farmers’ survey the follow<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee producers’ typology could be set up:Type 1 Type 2 Type 3 Type 4Large-scale wealthydiversified farmers with morethan 5 ha <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee (robustaand arabica), ra<strong>in</strong> fed rice,other crops (vegetables, fruittrees, etc.), cattle, pigs andpoultry. Many have othersources <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come.Mid-scale diversified c<strong>of</strong>feeproducers grow<strong>in</strong>g robustaand arabica besides othercrops (vegetables, ra<strong>in</strong> fedrice, fruit trees, etc.). Theymay own little livestock (fewcattle and small livestock),those who have a tok-tok cansell processed c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> Pakse.Small-scale diversified c<strong>of</strong>feeproducers grow<strong>in</strong>g robustaand some arabica besidesother crops (associated or notto c<strong>of</strong>fee plantations) andsome small cattle.Economically, they are heavilydependant on c<strong>of</strong>fee. They sella large percentage <strong>of</strong>unprocessed c<strong>of</strong>fee (especiallyarabica) and a significantpercentage makes pre-harvestloans.Small-scale non diversifiedfarmers heavily c<strong>of</strong>feedependantwith little livestockand little access to othersources <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. Asignificant percentage sellsunprocessed c<strong>of</strong>fee (especiallyarabica cherries) and makespre-harvest loans.Besides, some farmers gathered <strong>in</strong> export<strong>in</strong>g groups <strong>in</strong> order to produce high-quality arabica sold <strong>in</strong> nichemarkets. They have benefited from <strong>in</strong>ternational organizations support (Oxfam Australia, Jhai foundation,PAB, etc.).F<strong>in</strong>ally, a certa<strong>in</strong> number <strong>of</strong> private <strong>in</strong>vestors (generally foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors from Vietnam, Ch<strong>in</strong>a, Thailand,etc.) have set up arabica commercial plantations with very <strong>in</strong>tensive cropp<strong>in</strong>g systems <strong>in</strong> land concessionsgranted by local authorities. It was difficult to obta<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation on this issue as there is a lack <strong>of</strong>transparency. However, we can estimate the current c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces to around 1,200 ha. In the near future,this scheme is likely to develop more and more as prov<strong>in</strong>cial authorities have signed an agreement with aVietnamese company for the grant <strong>of</strong> further 1,000 to 5,000 ha.Limit<strong>in</strong>g factorsThere are some <strong>in</strong>tr<strong>in</strong>sic limit<strong>in</strong>g factors to c<strong>of</strong>fee production. Some have to do with c<strong>of</strong>fee primaryproduction such as pest control (especially C<strong>of</strong>fee Berry Borer), fertility and plantations’ management. Onthe other hand, there are issues regard<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee post-harvest techniques and more particularly thedry<strong>in</strong>g.There is also the specific issue <strong>of</strong> harvest labor as it stands for more than 60% <strong>of</strong> total production costs.Therefore, any variation <strong>of</strong> labor price or availability might have real impact on c<strong>of</strong>fee production. Thisissue cropped up quite recently with the <strong>in</strong>troduction <strong>of</strong> dwarf-variety arabica. Indeed, arabica harvest ismore workforce-demand<strong>in</strong>g than robusta (as it uses the selective pick<strong>in</strong>g) so when all newly set arabicaplantations will be mature, there will be a significant <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> external labor demand, at a period <strong>of</strong> theyear where labor is globally less available (competition with rice harvest <strong>in</strong> the lowlands).C<strong>of</strong>fee producers have already started to meet difficulties f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g external waged labor for arabicaharvest. Today, most harvest work is carried out by family workforce with a greater care <strong>of</strong> the quality.We have estimated that <strong>in</strong> 2012, global workforce demand for arabica harvest will be four times higher<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 10


than today; farmers will have to use more and more external waged labor with a problem <strong>of</strong> global laboravailability and harvest quality control. This evolution is very likely to be prejudicial to c<strong>of</strong>fee producersas it will surely <strong>in</strong>crease their production costs and could have a negative impact on f<strong>in</strong>al product’squality.C<strong>of</strong>fee commercializationMa<strong>in</strong> actorsFarmers can sell c<strong>of</strong>fee either to small-village buyers, wholesalers <strong>in</strong> district towns or directly to exporters.Many farmers still sell unprocessed products (arabica cherries and robusta dried-cherries) so the furtherprocess<strong>in</strong>g is carried out by other actors who have wet-mills, robusta c<strong>of</strong>fee-mills, dry<strong>in</strong>g areas, etc.Small buyers purchase quite small amounts (from 1 up to 100 tons) <strong>in</strong> their own village and <strong>in</strong>surround<strong>in</strong>g villages. They may work on their own or for an exporter. Besides c<strong>of</strong>fee purchas<strong>in</strong>g, villagebuyers are generally <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal credit through usury credit and pre-harvest loans.There are less than 10 wholesalers (they live <strong>in</strong> district towns <strong>of</strong> Paksong and <strong>Lao</strong>ngam). Their range <strong>of</strong>action <strong>in</strong>cludes 30 to 50 villages with<strong>in</strong> the limits <strong>of</strong> the district. Interviewed wholesalers purchasedbetween 200 and 500 MT <strong>of</strong> robusta and 100 to 200 MT <strong>of</strong> arabica dur<strong>in</strong>g 2006/2007 campaign. Besidesc<strong>of</strong>fee buy<strong>in</strong>g, most wholesalers also provide credit services to farmers through cash or rice loans, eitherfollow<strong>in</strong>g a traditional loan scheme or through pre-harvest loans.In <strong>Lao</strong>s, there is a monopole on c<strong>of</strong>fee exports by the companies registered <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee Association.C<strong>of</strong>fee export is largely dom<strong>in</strong>ated by one big company that commercializes around 70% <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeproduction. The rest is exported by less than five import-export companies closely l<strong>in</strong>ked to a smallnumber <strong>of</strong> importers’ local agents. Exporters have different strategies: some are import-export companies,others are c<strong>of</strong>fee planters (on land concessions) and c<strong>of</strong>fee roasters at the same time and some exportersare registered <strong>in</strong> the exporters’ association but never really deal physically with c<strong>of</strong>fee. They provide“export services” to other companies that don’t have an exporter license (like farmer groups).As regards c<strong>of</strong>fee buyers, a significant part <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee is purchased by <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee traders whohave local agents <strong>in</strong> Pakse. In the past few years, the market for <strong>Lao</strong> export c<strong>of</strong>fee has been largelydom<strong>in</strong>ated by two ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee traders whose agents <strong>in</strong> Pakse are very active.Export standardsIn <strong>Lao</strong>s, most exporters have specialized <strong>in</strong> the sell<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee (robusta and arabica) without any qualitystandards (called FAQ c<strong>of</strong>fee). As a consequence, most exporters haven’t set up the means to processc<strong>of</strong>fee accord<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>ternational quality standards. In most cases they merely proceed to a rough grad<strong>in</strong>gand a manual sort<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee beans. So far, only one company has set up the required <strong>in</strong>frastructure for af<strong>in</strong>e treatment <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee beans.Some farmers’ groups sell<strong>in</strong>g to niche markets have started to process c<strong>of</strong>fee follow<strong>in</strong>g more strict qualitystandards (set up by each buyer). However, most <strong>of</strong> the process is still manual (sort<strong>in</strong>g, clean<strong>in</strong>g, etc.).Export proceduresWe estimate the total export costs to 100 to 110 USD/MT (which stands for 4 to 6% <strong>of</strong> total value). Ma<strong>in</strong>costs are related to c<strong>of</strong>fee transport and more specifically the shipp<strong>in</strong>g through Thailand (70 USD/MT <strong>in</strong>average). Regard<strong>in</strong>g procedural costs, besides all the certificates that exporters must get before shipp<strong>in</strong>gthe product, the ma<strong>in</strong> expense concerns the tax on pr<strong>of</strong>it (around 30 USD/MT). In spite <strong>of</strong> a recent effort <strong>of</strong>clarification from the M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> F<strong>in</strong>ances, c<strong>of</strong>fee tax system rema<strong>in</strong>s opaque and is differently <strong>in</strong>terpretedby local authorities and ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee actors. F<strong>in</strong>ally, many exporters and c<strong>of</strong>fee traders compla<strong>in</strong> about the<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g number <strong>of</strong> un<strong>of</strong>ficial costs (dur<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee transport, certificates delivery, <strong>in</strong>ternational checkpo<strong>in</strong>ts, etc.).<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 11


Secondary actorsUnlike many c<strong>of</strong>fee export<strong>in</strong>g countries, the implication <strong>of</strong> secondary actors (governmental, f<strong>in</strong>ancial,scientific, etc.) is either non-existent or very weak. Ma<strong>in</strong> secondary actors are:• Several government and government-l<strong>in</strong>ked agents that <strong>in</strong>tervene at different levels <strong>of</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee<strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> (ma<strong>in</strong>ly the M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, the M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> Commerce and Industry, the F<strong>in</strong>ancedepartment, prov<strong>in</strong>cial and district authorities). Although there isn’t an <strong>in</strong>stitutional coord<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong>c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> actors, different governmental bodies are present at all levels <strong>of</strong> the <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>, howevertheir role is <strong>of</strong>ten limited to overall supervision, certificates delivery and tax collect<strong>in</strong>g. However, s<strong>in</strong>ce thepast 15 years, M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture has a very important implication <strong>in</strong> the sector through its projects(former LUAPD, <strong>PDR</strong>PB, FAO and now PCADR-PAB).• Banks and other credit suppliers: they ma<strong>in</strong>ly lend money to exporters for c<strong>of</strong>fee purchas<strong>in</strong>g and<strong>in</strong>vestment. Most farmers or small traders have simply no access to formal credit.• Agricultural <strong>in</strong>put suppliers: they ma<strong>in</strong>ly sell fertilizers and pesticides to some big-scale farmersand to commercial plantations.• Research <strong>in</strong>stitutions: the only c<strong>of</strong>fee-related research <strong>in</strong>stitution called CREC doesn’t carry out anyresearch program at the moment and depends for a great part on external projects’ opportunities.C<strong>of</strong>fee roast<strong>in</strong>g (for domestic market)<strong>Lao</strong>s has a small but very dynamic domestic market that uses almost exclusively downgraded exportc<strong>of</strong>fee (undersized and defective beans). A bunch <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustrial or semi-<strong>in</strong>dustrial roasters have specialized<strong>in</strong> the production <strong>of</strong> European-style c<strong>of</strong>fee (with a very large dom<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>of</strong> 3 very dynamic companies).On the other hand, a “local-style” c<strong>of</strong>fee is produced by a bunch <strong>of</strong> small and medium roast<strong>in</strong>g companiescharacterized by the use <strong>of</strong> hand-made roast<strong>in</strong>g mach<strong>in</strong>es and flavor additives. Every year, 400 to 500 tonsare transformed <strong>in</strong> local style c<strong>of</strong>fee and 200 to 300 tons become pure-roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee.In the past years, <strong>Lao</strong> roasters have managed to expand the domestic market by develop<strong>in</strong>g a wide range<strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee products us<strong>in</strong>g aggressive and effective market<strong>in</strong>g strategies. Besides the sell<strong>in</strong>g to traditionalretail<strong>in</strong>g places (m<strong>in</strong>i-marts, c<strong>of</strong>fee shops, restaurants, hotels, etc.), some roasters have set their ownconsumption places like specialized c<strong>of</strong>fee-shops, c<strong>of</strong>fee stands, etc. where they can sell c<strong>of</strong>fee beverageand advertise their products.The results from a recent cup tast<strong>in</strong>g tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g showed that many <strong>Lao</strong> roasted c<strong>of</strong>fees still have bigorganoleptic and physic defects. The global quality <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee rema<strong>in</strong>s quite low accord<strong>in</strong>g to<strong>in</strong>ternational standards. So far, this hasn’t had a repercussion as domestic costumers are quite new c<strong>of</strong>feeconsumers.Organization <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee market circuitsThere are three ma<strong>in</strong> circuits for <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee, listed <strong>in</strong> order <strong>of</strong> importance:• The ma<strong>in</strong>stream export circuit (that <strong>in</strong>cludes two types <strong>of</strong> product: natural robusta and mostwashed arabica)• The circuit <strong>of</strong> washed arabica for niche markets• The circuit <strong>of</strong> roasted-c<strong>of</strong>fee for domestic marketMore than 99% <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee is exported through ma<strong>in</strong>stream commercial circuits <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g 100% <strong>of</strong>robusta and most arabica. There is a low level <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee producers <strong>in</strong> all stages related toc<strong>of</strong>fee process<strong>in</strong>g (especially <strong>in</strong> the case <strong>of</strong> arabica) if compared with other export<strong>in</strong>g countries.Another remarkable fact is the relative shortness <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>stream circuit <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>. Indeed, not only arethere few categories <strong>of</strong> agents <strong>in</strong>volved (producers, village buyers, wholesalers and exporters) but almosthalf <strong>of</strong> the farmers (<strong>in</strong> the case <strong>of</strong> robusta) sell c<strong>of</strong>fee directly to exporters.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 12


Product quality control system is <strong>in</strong>sufficient at all stages <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee commercialization. F<strong>in</strong>al product isaverage quality green c<strong>of</strong>fee (FAQ) for which there is a great demand but that suffers from a price penalty(accord<strong>in</strong>g to most exporters).A very small quantity <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee (around 100 MT/year) is marketed through niche market circuits (less than0.5% <strong>of</strong> total c<strong>of</strong>fee exports). Ma<strong>in</strong> actors <strong>of</strong> this circuit are <strong>Lao</strong>tian producers’ groups supported byNGOs. C<strong>of</strong>fee is generally sold to foreign roast<strong>in</strong>g companies specialized <strong>in</strong> high-quality Fair Tradespecialty c<strong>of</strong>fees.Generally farmers pulp arabica c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> collective pulp<strong>in</strong>g mach<strong>in</strong>es and sell parchment c<strong>of</strong>fee to thegroup or cooperative. Technical staff tra<strong>in</strong>ed by support<strong>in</strong>g organizations and paid by farmers’ groupsensures the technical follow up and check that c<strong>of</strong>fee matches buyers’ quality standards. Farmers obta<strong>in</strong>the Fair Trade price for South-east Asia plus a fair-trade bonus. Then, the group deduces all costs relatedto c<strong>of</strong>fee process, salaries, material, etc. In 2006, price paid to producers ranged from 19,000 to 21,000Kip/Kg (1.95-2.16 USD/Kg).Relations between ma<strong>in</strong> actorsRelations between producers and c<strong>of</strong>fee buyersPre-harvest loansFarmers can sell their produce either dur<strong>in</strong>g harvest period or <strong>in</strong> advance <strong>in</strong> exchange <strong>of</strong> pre-harvest loans(farmers say they sell “green c<strong>of</strong>fee” or “café khiaw” <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>). Among farmers’ survey sample 8 , 45% <strong>of</strong> the<strong>in</strong>terviewed farmers borrowed money through this system last year, and more particularly poorestfarmers. There are different loan modalities: farmers can either reimburse <strong>in</strong> money (actually theyreimburse while sell<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee, at market’s price and with monthly <strong>in</strong>terest rates rang<strong>in</strong>g from 15 to 25%)or <strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee, with no <strong>in</strong>terest rate but with a sell<strong>in</strong>g price which is about half the average market price.In both cases the scheme <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sell<strong>in</strong>g disadvantages a quality system as the priority for farmers isma<strong>in</strong>ly the c<strong>of</strong>fee volume (they have to reimburse their debt) and they cannot benefit from thecompetition between c<strong>of</strong>fee buyers.In average, farmers borrow money 7 to 10 months before the harvest and generally borrow less than 1million Kip (around 100 USD). Beside the payment <strong>of</strong> external waged labor, these loans are ma<strong>in</strong>ly used tobuy rice or to provide for exceptional expenses such as illness or religious ceremonies. A small percentage<strong>of</strong> the families <strong>in</strong>terviewed (around 5%) have made pre-harvest loans every s<strong>in</strong>gle year dur<strong>in</strong>g the past 5years.C<strong>of</strong>fee sell<strong>in</strong>g dur<strong>in</strong>g harvest periodDur<strong>in</strong>g 2006/2007 campaign, 64% <strong>of</strong> the farmers sold unprocessed arabica (mostly cherries) and 45% soldunprocessed robusta (mostly dried-cherries). In terms <strong>of</strong> percentage <strong>of</strong> total harvest, 42% <strong>of</strong> arabicaharvest was sold as unprocessed c<strong>of</strong>fee versus 21% for robusta. As a comparison, <strong>in</strong> 1999 around 95% <strong>of</strong>robusta c<strong>of</strong>fee was sold as dried-cherries (<strong>PDR</strong>PB, 1999). The explanation is that many farmers have to sellarabica cherries as it is a very perishable product that requires to be processed almost immediately.Robusta dried-cherries can be kept <strong>in</strong> the farm until farmers have the possibility to shell it <strong>in</strong> a village mill.Arabica is ma<strong>in</strong>ly sold to village area buyers whereas 50% <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>terviewed farmers sold robusta directly toexporters. The ma<strong>in</strong> reason is that more and more farmers have had access to transportation means andespecially tok-toks.Buy<strong>in</strong>g prices are always decided by the buyer as farmers have very little power <strong>of</strong> negotiation.8 A specific survey on c<strong>of</strong>fee sell<strong>in</strong>g was carried out <strong>in</strong> half <strong>of</strong> the households <strong>of</strong> the total sample, that is to say 200 households <strong>in</strong> 20villages.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 13


Relations between exporters and upstream suppliersMost exporters buy most <strong>of</strong> their c<strong>of</strong>fee from middlemen and producers (except for planter-exporters).They ensure their c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> through simple verbal agreements or through the sett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> real contractswith some middle-buyers. In some cases they f<strong>in</strong>ance c<strong>of</strong>fee buy<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the first place by lend<strong>in</strong>g money tomiddle-buyers or producers or by giv<strong>in</strong>g money advances to c<strong>of</strong>fee collectors. They might provide othertypes <strong>of</strong> credit services such as the lend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee trees.C<strong>of</strong>fee prices structureBased on <strong>in</strong>formation collected from ma<strong>in</strong> actors, it was possible to set up an estimated price structure foreach c<strong>of</strong>fee market circuit.One <strong>of</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>of</strong> this <strong>analysis</strong> is the lack <strong>of</strong> clearness about the price penalty for <strong>Lao</strong> orig<strong>in</strong>c<strong>of</strong>fee. Indeed, when we compared the average contract price given by exporters with <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>feeprices, it appeared that the difference is almost twice higher than announced by most c<strong>of</strong>fee agents. Thiscould be due to a difference between the contract prices and some actors’ marg<strong>in</strong>s and reality.The study also showed some differences <strong>in</strong> export costs between the ma<strong>in</strong>stream and niche marketcircuits. The ma<strong>in</strong> reason is a higher procedural cost for farmers’ export groups as they pay higher localtaxes and have to pay a commission to a LCA export<strong>in</strong>g company (for export procedures).The next figure presents the <strong>analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> the value <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> for each c<strong>of</strong>fee circuit through the distribution <strong>of</strong>the f<strong>in</strong>al value amongst ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> actors.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee circuits value <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong>100%F<strong>in</strong>al value distribution amongst ma<strong>in</strong> actors80%% <strong>of</strong> f<strong>in</strong>al value60%40%20%0%Producer Middle man Exporter Trader/RoasterRobusta FAQArabica CherriesArabica National MarketArabica ParchmentArabica Fair TradeProducers obta<strong>in</strong> the highest percentages <strong>of</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al value <strong>in</strong> the niche market circuit (73.2%) and <strong>in</strong> thema<strong>in</strong>stream FAQ robusta circuit (60%). On the contrary, they only get 32% <strong>of</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al value when theysell arabica cherries. In that case, the added value is retrieved by middlemen who carry out the wetprocess.In the case <strong>of</strong> roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee circuit, roasters obta<strong>in</strong> almost 80% <strong>of</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al product’s value.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 14


ConclusionsMa<strong>in</strong> strengths <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector are related to the product itself and its potential markets. The countryhasn’t yet exploited all the possibilities l<strong>in</strong>ked to the uniqueness and typicity <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee and speciallyrobusta (except for some small-scale experiences <strong>of</strong> arabica c<strong>of</strong>fee sold to niche markets). A dynamicdomestic market has developed but domestic consumption rema<strong>in</strong>s low and roasters only useundergraded export c<strong>of</strong>fee.In order to develop high-quality c<strong>of</strong>fee, <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector must cont<strong>in</strong>ue to promote the build<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> wetprocess<strong>in</strong>gunits <strong>in</strong> produc<strong>in</strong>g villages as it has been done through the sett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> farmers’ groups(supported by external <strong>in</strong>stitutions such as PAB, Oxfam or Jhai). Moreover, a fair and accessible system <strong>of</strong>f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>in</strong>dividual farmers must be set up. F<strong>in</strong>ally, at <strong>in</strong>stitutional level, national authorities shouldset up c<strong>of</strong>fee quality standards as well as a control body (laboratory) <strong>in</strong> order to project a pr<strong>of</strong>essional andclear image <strong>in</strong>ternationally.This evolution should be accompanied by a global reflection about environment protection policy as wellas a prospective <strong>analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> the potential impact <strong>of</strong> land concessions <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 15


IntroductionC<strong>of</strong>fee sector <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s has spectacularly developed with<strong>in</strong> the last 15 years,. This development can becharacterized by the comb<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong>: a significant <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> production; the com<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> new actors; thedevelopment <strong>of</strong> a dynamic domestic market and a certa<strong>in</strong> improvement <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee image <strong>in</strong> foreignmarkets. This recent but rapid development has brought significant changes at different levels, for<strong>in</strong>stance:• At production level, c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces have almost doubled <strong>in</strong> the past 10 years and the share <strong>of</strong>arabica have been steadily <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g with the sett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> new plantations by both farmers andprivate <strong>in</strong>vestors.• At technical level, some producers have progressively been hav<strong>in</strong>g access to the c<strong>of</strong>fee wetmethodprocess<strong>in</strong>g technique, which allows the production <strong>of</strong> high quality c<strong>of</strong>fee (essentially forarabica).• At market level, both domestic and export markets have significantly grown; <strong>in</strong>deed, domesticconsumption has steadily <strong>in</strong>creased and consumers are now <strong>of</strong>fered a wide range <strong>of</strong> products.Regard<strong>in</strong>g exports, not only the exports volumes have <strong>in</strong>creased, but <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee has also managedto enter some niche markets with a high quality image.However, this dynamic has relied for a great part on an auspicious environment: <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>feeprices have allowed pr<strong>of</strong>itability with local production costs and the <strong>in</strong>ternational market for <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeseems to be quite expandable. In fact, all these changes have taken place without any k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> sectorstrategy as <strong>Lao</strong>s doesn’t have an entity <strong>in</strong> charge <strong>of</strong> guid<strong>in</strong>g and coord<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> actors.The risk is that <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector rema<strong>in</strong>s completely liable to the external context.With the view <strong>of</strong> limit<strong>in</strong>g and controll<strong>in</strong>g this external <strong>in</strong>fluence, most c<strong>of</strong>fee produc<strong>in</strong>g countries have setstructures that gather ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector stakeholders. Called either C<strong>of</strong>fee Board or C<strong>of</strong>fee Council, theseentities are generally <strong>in</strong> charge <strong>of</strong>: (i) advis<strong>in</strong>g national authorities on the future strategy for c<strong>of</strong>fee sector;(ii) be the representative organism who promotes country’s product <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational events and f<strong>in</strong>ally (iii)controll<strong>in</strong>g all laws and regulations related to c<strong>of</strong>fee.Consider<strong>in</strong>g that and <strong>in</strong> order to fill this <strong>in</strong>stitutional gap, ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee actors, <strong>Lao</strong> authorities as well asdevelopment projects work<strong>in</strong>g on these issues decided to gather <strong>in</strong> a reflection group called the GTC(“Groupe de Travail Café” or C<strong>of</strong>fee Work<strong>in</strong>g Group). Its mission is to assess the current situation <strong>of</strong>c<strong>of</strong>fee sector <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s and provide recommendations <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> strategy. The work <strong>of</strong> the GTC shouldresult <strong>in</strong> the creation <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee board, which will be probably called the CNCL (“Conseil Nationaldu Café <strong>Lao</strong>” <strong>in</strong> French).The GTC has two ma<strong>in</strong> objectives. The first one is to make propositions to national authorities regard<strong>in</strong>gfuture C<strong>of</strong>fee Board’s <strong>in</strong>stitutional frame (<strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> structure, regulation, f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g, etc.). The secondobjective is to carry out a participative <strong>analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> that can be used as a basis to theelaboration <strong>of</strong> the future c<strong>of</strong>fee sector mid-term and long-term strategy.The c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> study took place between May and November 2007. Its ma<strong>in</strong> resultscome from data collected <strong>in</strong> the field, <strong>in</strong>terviews with ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee actors, available bibliography andfurther discussions with GTC participants. The current report <strong>in</strong>tends to summarize and analyze the ma<strong>in</strong>f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>of</strong> this study.The first three sections provide an overall review <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s by present<strong>in</strong>g its history andrecent developments; we first present the place <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee market beforeshortly present<strong>in</strong>g the role <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector <strong>in</strong> national economy. In the fourth section, <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong><strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> is described and analyzed through the characterization <strong>of</strong> its ma<strong>in</strong> actors and their activities, then,ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee circuits and the relations between c<strong>of</strong>fee actors are analyzed <strong>in</strong> section five. F<strong>in</strong>ally, the<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 16


esults’ <strong>in</strong>terpretation should lead to the identification <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> issues and bottlenecks for c<strong>of</strong>fee sectordevelopment and then to practical recommendations <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> strategy, emphasiz<strong>in</strong>g those that mightbe undertaken by the future c<strong>of</strong>fee board.1. Some elements <strong>of</strong> methodology1.1. Def<strong>in</strong>itions and conceptsThe “<strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>” or “value <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>” (“filière” <strong>in</strong> French) is def<strong>in</strong>ed as the set <strong>of</strong> complementary or<strong>in</strong>terdependent activities located at different steps <strong>of</strong> the production process from producer to consumer.It <strong>in</strong>volves the flows <strong>of</strong> products, money and <strong>in</strong>formation, as well as ma<strong>in</strong> actors’ strategies as illustrated<strong>in</strong> Fabre et al def<strong>in</strong>ition (1996): « A <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> is the set <strong>of</strong> economic actors and their relations, whichcontribute to the production, process<strong>in</strong>g, distribution and consumption <strong>of</strong> a product ».Malassis and Ghersi (1996) add that the identification <strong>of</strong> the <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> sheds light on the enterprises,<strong>in</strong>stitutions, operations, as well as the volumes, barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g capacities, technologies, production relations,prices structure, etc. Different markets exist<strong>in</strong>g throughout a product’s <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> cannot be describedthrough a pure and perfect competition model. In the real world, many <strong>in</strong>stitutions, regulations, personaland bus<strong>in</strong>ess relations <strong>in</strong>terfere with the decisions and the def<strong>in</strong>itions <strong>of</strong> markets and prices. This is whythey must be taken <strong>in</strong>to account. Besides, a product’s <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> must be analyzed as a whole complexsystem and not just as the result <strong>of</strong> <strong>supply</strong> and demand. Indeed:• As a product circulates from production to distribution-retail, it is exchanged on not just one, butseveral markets: production or rural markets; wholesale markets at exportation level; retail<strong>in</strong>gmarkets, etc.• The nature and type <strong>of</strong> the product also changes all along the <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>. Producers sell red cherries, driedcherries, parchment or green c<strong>of</strong>fee. Traders sell sorted-dried-commercial c<strong>of</strong>fee. Retailers sell roastedc<strong>of</strong>fee, <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fees, 3 <strong>in</strong> 1 <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fees, etc.• For each <strong>of</strong> these steps, there are dist<strong>in</strong>ct categories <strong>of</strong> actors and stakeholders: large and small-scale,oriented towards national or export markets, specialized <strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee or diversified, etc. They do not havethe same goals/strategy, nor do they have the same constra<strong>in</strong>ts.The methodology that will be f<strong>in</strong>ally chosen must take <strong>in</strong>to account all these aspects and must allow aglobal understand<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector, actors, relations, etc.1.2. Methodological frameworkThere are several methods to describe and analyze the path <strong>of</strong> an agricultural product among the differentstages from production to consumption. In the scope <strong>of</strong> this study, it has been decided to choose theapproach <strong>of</strong> the participative <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> proposed by Bourgeois and Herrera (1998) alsoknown as the Cadiac method. This method analyses a product <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g five ma<strong>in</strong> stages:Table 1: Ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>’s <strong>analysis</strong> stepsAnalysis stagesGeneral context <strong>analysis</strong>Relations with nationaleconomySupply <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> structureSupply <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> function<strong>in</strong>gResults’ <strong>in</strong>terpretationMa<strong>in</strong> issuesRelations <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector with <strong>in</strong>ternational economy., markets, trade agreements, etc.Economic and social relevance <strong>of</strong> the <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>in</strong> national economy, domesticconsumption, policies and <strong>in</strong>stitutions.Identification and characterization <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> stakeholders and activities (typology,upstream and downstream <strong>supply</strong>, etc.)Identification and characterization <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> circuits, dynamics and regulationStrengths and limit<strong>in</strong>g factors <strong>of</strong> the sector.Indicators, perspectives and different scenarios <strong>of</strong> evolution.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 17


In this study, we tried to collect as much first-hand <strong>in</strong>formation as possible; most <strong>in</strong>formation wascollected either through surveys or through <strong>in</strong>terviews with ma<strong>in</strong> stakeholders and f<strong>in</strong>ally validated byc<strong>of</strong>fee sector actors <strong>in</strong> the scope <strong>of</strong> the GTC. However, some relevant <strong>in</strong>formation such as macro-economic<strong>in</strong>dicators can only be collected through <strong>in</strong>direct methods or through available bibliography. In that casespecial attention is given to data reliability (verification, crosscheck<strong>in</strong>g, etc.).The follow<strong>in</strong>g table summarizes the ma<strong>in</strong> sources <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation used <strong>in</strong> this study and the ma<strong>in</strong> datacollection tools that were used:Table 2: Ma<strong>in</strong> study’s data collect toolsIssue Sources Data collection toolsC<strong>of</strong>fee primaryproductionC<strong>of</strong>fee buy<strong>in</strong>g, preharvest-loansPrivate <strong>in</strong>vestorsIndustrial process<strong>in</strong>gExportRetail<strong>in</strong>g (domesticmarket)ConsumptionRegulations,<strong>in</strong>stitutional frame,trade agreements, etc.Statistic household survey <strong>in</strong> 400households <strong>of</strong> 20 villages <strong>of</strong> the BolovenPlateauInterviews with 21 small-scale villagebuyers from 20 different villages and 3wholesalers from Paksong and <strong>Lao</strong>ngamdistrict townsPrivate <strong>in</strong>vestors and prov<strong>in</strong>cialauthoritiesInterviews with 11 roast<strong>in</strong>g companies <strong>in</strong>Pakse and VientianeInterviews with 8 major c<strong>of</strong>fee exporters<strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee AssociationX ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee importersVisit <strong>of</strong> 42 c<strong>of</strong>fee retailers <strong>in</strong> Vientiane andPakseC<strong>of</strong>fee retailersConsumers (170: <strong>Lao</strong>tians and foreigners)M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Forestry(MAF), M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> Commerce andIndustry, Food and Drugs Department,<strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee Association, prov<strong>in</strong>cialauthorities <strong>of</strong> Champasak and Saravan,UC-PCADR, PAB, etc.Household questionnaires on c<strong>of</strong>feeproduction, c<strong>of</strong>fee sell<strong>in</strong>g and labor issuesMiddle-buyer questionnairesProv<strong>in</strong>cial authorities statistics and <strong>in</strong>formal<strong>in</strong>terviewsRoasters’ questionnairesExporters’ questionnaireStatistics from the <strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee AssociationImporters’ e-mail questionnairesRetailers’ questionnairesC<strong>of</strong>fee products characterizationRetailers’ questionnaires (<strong>in</strong>direct <strong>in</strong>formation)Prelim<strong>in</strong>ary results <strong>of</strong> a c<strong>of</strong>fee market studycarried out by a student <strong>in</strong> the scope <strong>of</strong> sett<strong>in</strong>gup <strong>of</strong> a Geographical Indication for <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeInformal <strong>in</strong>terviewsStatistic data availableBibliographyWorkshop on c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong>with<strong>in</strong> the GTC<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 18


2. A brief review <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s and its recentdevelopmentIn this section we give a quick overview <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s as regards its history and recentevolutions. The aim is to give some elements <strong>of</strong> explanation that allow an understand<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sectortoday.2.1. History <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>sThe beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s (1920-1950)The first c<strong>of</strong>fee plantations <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau were set around 1920 by French settlers alongside theroads built by the colonial adm<strong>in</strong>istration. C<strong>of</strong>fee rapidly became the ma<strong>in</strong> crop <strong>in</strong> the area, especiallyafter the construction <strong>of</strong> a research center near Paksong <strong>in</strong> 1930 (Ban Lak 42). At that time, settlers grewexclusively arabica trees <strong>of</strong> Bourbon and Typica varieties. With<strong>in</strong> few years, native farmers liv<strong>in</strong>g nearcolonial plantations started to grow c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> small gardens, and then real c<strong>of</strong>fee plantations from 1940. Atits maximum level, c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces <strong>in</strong> the Boloven reached 5,000 ha. (Bab<strong>in</strong>, 1998).At that time c<strong>of</strong>fee was entirely processed follow<strong>in</strong>g the wet method and all technical steps (pulp<strong>in</strong>g,ferment<strong>in</strong>g, wash<strong>in</strong>g, etc.) were made manually. The c<strong>of</strong>fee obta<strong>in</strong>ed was then ma<strong>in</strong>ly exported to Francewith a very high-quality image.War and c<strong>of</strong>fee sector deliquescence (1950-1975)From 1950 onwards, several external factors trigger a disorganization <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s. In the firstplace, there was a progressive dismantlement <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee market<strong>in</strong>g network, downstream with the SecondWorld War and upstream when ma<strong>in</strong> planters, <strong>in</strong>vestors and traders flee the zone because <strong>of</strong> the recurrentconflicts. In the same time, colonial arabica plantations were be<strong>in</strong>g severely damaged by recurrent frostsand more particularly by leaf rust disease attacks. The first consequence was the progressiveabandonment <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee plantations by native farmers who had to focus on food crops. The secondconsequence was the progressive replacement <strong>of</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fea arabica Typica trees with newly <strong>in</strong>troduced speciesresistant to leaf rust, ma<strong>in</strong>ly C<strong>of</strong>fea canephora (commonly called robusta) and <strong>in</strong> a lesser extent C<strong>of</strong>fealiberica. In a context <strong>of</strong> war and production deliquescence these new species had many advantages: notonly they required less workforce and allowed higher yields, but the time and workforce required forc<strong>of</strong>fee harvest<strong>in</strong>g and process<strong>in</strong>g was also reduced as C. canephora is processed with the dry method withvery little care <strong>of</strong> cherries’ quality dur<strong>in</strong>g and after the harvest.The preem<strong>in</strong>ence <strong>of</strong> robusta <strong>in</strong> a state-controlled c<strong>of</strong>fee sector (1975-1990)After 1975 and the end <strong>of</strong> the war, native farmers as well as new settlers from the lowlands started toreoccupy the abandoned lands <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau. In the same time, new authorities set acollectivization program that <strong>in</strong>cluded the creation <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee production and trad<strong>in</strong>g cooperatives (Sallée,2007); as a result, the c<strong>of</strong>fee sector became State-controlled: collection, trad<strong>in</strong>g, export<strong>in</strong>g as well as prices’policies were controlled by national authorities with a view <strong>of</strong> high-production and little care <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feequality. This system didn’t allow great pr<strong>of</strong>itability.Dur<strong>in</strong>g this period, c<strong>of</strong>fee export benefits were ma<strong>in</strong>ly used to reimburse the Comecom debt with formersocialist countries. Under this market<strong>in</strong>g system the price <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee resulted from a bilateralnegotiation and didn’t reflect the state <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational markets (Matsushima, 2004). This productiondirectedpolicy triggered a drop <strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee quality as farmers took less care <strong>of</strong> their plantations andsimplified harvest and post-harvest practices (focus<strong>in</strong>g on c<strong>of</strong>fee volumes to the detriment <strong>of</strong> quality).Market liberalization and the resurgence <strong>of</strong> arabica (1990-2007)In the late 80’s, under the New Economic Mechanism regime (NEM), c<strong>of</strong>fee sector was progressivelyliberalized and private operators could f<strong>in</strong>ally enter it (Matsushima, 2004). The convergence <strong>of</strong> different<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 19


situations such as a new economic conjuncture, a dramatic rise <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee prices <strong>in</strong> 1994 due to frosts <strong>in</strong>Brazil and the devaluation <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> Kip <strong>in</strong> comparison with the dollar <strong>in</strong> 1997 follow<strong>in</strong>g the Asian crisistriggered a spectacular development <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee export sector. Indeed, despite a period <strong>of</strong> depletion <strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee prices between 1998 and 2003, the advantageous currency exchange rate policyallowed to keep c<strong>of</strong>fee sector pr<strong>of</strong>itability. As a consequence, <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exports steadily <strong>in</strong>creased dur<strong>in</strong>gthis whole period.Until the late 90’s, the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> production had ma<strong>in</strong>ly been made through <strong>of</strong> the extension <strong>of</strong> C.canephora plantations so <strong>in</strong> 2000, it represented more than 95% <strong>of</strong> total c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces. In the early 90’s,national authorities had started to promote arabica production through two ma<strong>in</strong> development projects:LUADP 9 (1991-1995) and <strong>PDR</strong>PB (1997-2002). One <strong>of</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> objectives <strong>of</strong> these projects was to developan <strong>in</strong>tensive cropp<strong>in</strong>g system us<strong>in</strong>g the high-productive dwarf variety 10 <strong>of</strong> arabica called Catimor. Thisvariety requires more workforce than C. canephora as regards grow<strong>in</strong>g, harvest<strong>in</strong>g and process<strong>in</strong>g. Indeed,as most arabicas, cherries from Catimor are processed follow<strong>in</strong>g the wet method. Despite the greaterdemand <strong>in</strong> workforce for this cropp<strong>in</strong>g system (to such a po<strong>in</strong>t that farmers call it the “K<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee”),farmers and <strong>in</strong>vestors are very attracted to it as c<strong>of</strong>fee is sold at higher prices <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational markets.Besides, arabica has a better image <strong>in</strong> import<strong>in</strong>g countries and <strong>of</strong>fers the possibility to enter high valueniche markets.The result <strong>of</strong> this policy has been a steady <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> arabica share dur<strong>in</strong>g the past 10 years to such extentit now stands for almost 15 % <strong>of</strong> the total c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee has 100 years <strong>of</strong> history. Its <strong>in</strong>ternational reputation was built on high-qualitywashed arabica from Bourbon and Typica varieties (1920-1950). Between 1950 and 1990,external factors (war, diseases) made that arabica was progressively replaced by C.canephora (robusta) so <strong>Lao</strong>s specialized <strong>in</strong> the production <strong>of</strong> natural robusta with noquality standards. S<strong>in</strong>ce 1990, there is a policy <strong>of</strong> re<strong>in</strong>troduction <strong>of</strong> arabica us<strong>in</strong>g a highproductivedwarf-variety with a slight but progressive adoption <strong>of</strong> the wet-method.2.2. Some facts on c<strong>of</strong>fee production2.2.1. Production areaAlthough some c<strong>of</strong>fee is produced <strong>in</strong> Northern prov<strong>in</strong>ces like Luang Prabang or Phongsaly, this studywill focus on Southern prov<strong>in</strong>ces, and more particularly on the Boloven Plateau as it stands for more than99% <strong>of</strong> total <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee production. Production is more specifically concentrated <strong>in</strong> the districts <strong>of</strong> Paksong<strong>in</strong> Champasak prov<strong>in</strong>ce, <strong>Lao</strong>ngam <strong>in</strong> Saravan and Thateng <strong>in</strong> Sekong.Table 3: Total c<strong>of</strong>fee area and production by region <strong>in</strong> 2004-2005Area (ha) Production (MT*)Northern Region 125 80Central Region 30 20Southern Region 42,425 24,900TOTAL 42,580 25,000Detail <strong>of</strong> Southern Region production by prov<strong>in</strong>ce:Champasak 25,100 14,610Saravan 13,100 7,830Sekong 3,865 2,200Attapeu 360 260*MT <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee9 See abbreviations’ <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>in</strong> page 510 Catimors are descendencies <strong>of</strong> a cross between Caturra and Timor Hybrid, resistant to c<strong>of</strong>fee leaf rust<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 20


Source: Agricultural Statistics Year Book 2006. M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> AgricultureThe Boloven Plateau is located at a latitude <strong>of</strong> 15° N, which engenders a strong seasonality with hotsummers and relatively cold w<strong>in</strong>ters. Altitudes range from 400 to 1400 m with a strong vertical agroecologicaldifferentiation.The Boloven Plateau is a very suitable place for arabica grow<strong>in</strong>g as it provides an excellent agro-ecologicenvironment for the grow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> this East-Africa native specie (See Annex 1 <strong>in</strong> page 80). In the first place,altitude attenuates the great variability <strong>of</strong> monsoons and regular dry-season ra<strong>in</strong>falls allow c<strong>of</strong>feeflower<strong>in</strong>g and vegetation ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g. Besides, the relatively cool climate (between November andFebruary) allows an adequate vegetative development <strong>in</strong> the same time it confers organoleptic qualities toc<strong>of</strong>fee. F<strong>in</strong>ally, Plateau’s rich-acid-deep soils are perfectly suitable for high-demand<strong>in</strong>g specie such as C.arabica. C. arabica naturally grows <strong>in</strong> altitudes rang<strong>in</strong>g from 800-900 m up to 1400 m. Its upperdevelopment limit is determ<strong>in</strong>ed by frost risks whereas its bottom limit depends on the amount <strong>of</strong> dryseasonra<strong>in</strong>falls.Surpris<strong>in</strong>gly, the Boloven Plateau is not the most suitable place for the ma<strong>in</strong> specie grown <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s, C<strong>of</strong>feacanephora, which is native <strong>of</strong> Wets-African lowland ra<strong>in</strong>-forests. In <strong>Lao</strong>s, C. canephora is grown <strong>in</strong> altitudesrang<strong>in</strong>g from 400 to 1400 m. In high altitudes, C. canephora hardly bear low temperatures which <strong>of</strong>ten leadto flower abortions. In low altitudes (between 400 and 800 m) trees suffer from a lack <strong>of</strong> water withrecurrent defoliations. In such altitudes, it is quite common that flower<strong>in</strong>g ra<strong>in</strong>s (March) are followed bydrought episodes which causes massive flower abortions, which leads to a drop <strong>of</strong> global production as ithappened <strong>in</strong> 2004 and 2005 (see export figures <strong>in</strong> 2005 and 2006 <strong>in</strong> Figure 2 page 24). However, thanks toits resistance (robustness) and strong adaptation capacity, C. canephora managed to adapt to theenvironment <strong>of</strong> the Boloven Plateau.In <strong>Lao</strong>s, the <strong>in</strong>troduction <strong>of</strong> robusta <strong>in</strong> a zone that is more suitable for arabica grow<strong>in</strong>g resulted fromhistorical reasons (war, diseases). The unexpected consequence <strong>of</strong> this situation is that <strong>Lao</strong>s is the onlyrobusta produc<strong>in</strong>g country <strong>in</strong> which C. canephora is grown at such latitude (15°) and altitude (400-1400m). Only Uganda grows robusta at quite high altitudes (below 900 m) with the difference that theproduction area is located near the Equator.C<strong>of</strong>fee, <strong>in</strong> general, is the ma<strong>in</strong> crop for a large majority <strong>of</strong> families. In altitudes below 800-900 m, familiesgrow mostly robusta (mixed with some Liberica trees); above 800-900 m, beside robusta, farmers havestarted to plant dwarf arabica trees <strong>in</strong> new areas or <strong>in</strong>side old robusta plantations. Many <strong>of</strong> these newplantations are not productive yet. Besides c<strong>of</strong>fee, farmers develop other activities ma<strong>in</strong>ly l<strong>in</strong>ked toagriculture and livestock breed<strong>in</strong>g.Table 4: Other productive activities <strong>in</strong> the Boloven PlateauCrop / Livestock % <strong>of</strong> farmers Average surface / number <strong>of</strong> animalsRice 20% 0.5 to 1 haOther crops (vegetables, fruit trees) 30% 0.5 haCattle 15% 8 to 10Pigs 30% 2 to 3Source: Producers’ survey (2007)2.2.2. C<strong>of</strong>fee productsThe two ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee species grown <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s are C<strong>of</strong>fea arabica and C<strong>of</strong>fea canephora which have differentbotanical, productive and taste characteristics 11 (see Annex 1 <strong>in</strong> page 80). In a much smaller scale there arealso some plants <strong>of</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fea liberica.11 In import<strong>in</strong>g countries, washed arabica is considered as a high quality c<strong>of</strong>fee and is ma<strong>in</strong>ly consumed as drip c<strong>of</strong>fee. On thecontrary, robusta is still considered a cheap and low quality c<strong>of</strong>fee and is ma<strong>in</strong>ly used to make c<strong>of</strong>fee blends or <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fees.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 21


All robusta exported from <strong>Lao</strong>s is obta<strong>in</strong>ed through the dry method; it means that immediately afterharvest, cherry beans are sun dried (the product obta<strong>in</strong>ed is called dried cherries) and then hulled <strong>in</strong> orderto obta<strong>in</strong> unsorted merchantable green c<strong>of</strong>fee (see Annex 3 <strong>in</strong> page 81). In many cases farmers dry thecherries on the bare ground as very few have set wooden or cemented dry<strong>in</strong>g areas. The f<strong>in</strong>al output <strong>of</strong>dry-process (after shell<strong>in</strong>g, sort<strong>in</strong>g and grad<strong>in</strong>g) is called “natural robusta” green c<strong>of</strong>fee.Arabica c<strong>of</strong>fee exported from <strong>Lao</strong>s is actually a mix between beans from the old Typica variety and thenewly <strong>in</strong>troduced dwarf variety (Catimor), with a high predom<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>of</strong> the latter. In most cases exportersand buyers do not make the difference and both varieties are mixed. The only exceptions are some FairTrade, Gourmet and other niche markets who specifically ask for 100% Typica beans. Most arabica isprocessed with “wet method”. After harvest, selected red cherries are pulped, fermented and washedwith water before be<strong>in</strong>g dried. The product obta<strong>in</strong>ed is called “washed arabica” or “fully washedarabica”. In <strong>Lao</strong>s, unripe or defective arabica beans are <strong>of</strong>ten processed follow<strong>in</strong>g the dry method andsold either <strong>in</strong> the domestic market (roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee) or <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ternational market as “unwashed” or“natural” arabica.2.2.3. Recent evolution <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee productionFigure 1: Evolution <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces and production <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s (1976-2005)4500040000350003000025000200001500010000500001976197819801982198419861988Area Harvested (ha)19901992199419961998Production (MT)200020022004Source: Yearly statistics from the M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> AgricultureThis graph made from <strong>of</strong>ficial statistics shows that global c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces and production have beensteadily <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g for the past 30 years. However, as no breakdown by specie is available, it is notpossible to see the different dynamics between robusta and arabica. What we know is that before 1990,C. canephora (robusta) represented more than 95% <strong>of</strong> total c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces. The rapid <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feesurfaces and production observed s<strong>in</strong>ce 1995 is ma<strong>in</strong>ly the result <strong>of</strong> the sett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> new arabica plantations(promoted by local authorities and different projects such as LUADP, <strong>PDR</strong>PB, FAO c<strong>of</strong>fee project, etc.).Table 5: Evolution <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces and species share <strong>in</strong> the Boloven PlateauYear Total surface (ha) Robusta % Arabica % Source1990 17,066 > 99 % Residual Typica <strong>PDR</strong>PB1999 25,000 98,5 % 1,5 % (Duris, 2000)2007 45,000 87 % 13 %Extrapolation from PAB figuresand producers’ survey 2007Table 5 shows the evolution <strong>of</strong> robusta and arabica surfaces s<strong>in</strong>ce 1990. As no <strong>of</strong>ficial statistics areavailable, figures were taken from different sources. We observe that the greater <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> arabicasurfaces took place s<strong>in</strong>ce 1999 as the share <strong>of</strong> arabica went from less than 2% to 13% <strong>of</strong> total surfaces. In<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 22


Table 6 we present the current productive situation <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau and specially a prospect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong>arabica surfaces.Table 6: Boloven Plateau c<strong>of</strong>fee productive situation <strong>in</strong> 2007Robusta(ha)Production(MT greenc<strong>of</strong>fee)Arabica(ha)Production(MT greenc<strong>of</strong>fee)Youngunproductivearabicasurfaces (ha)Nurseries(number <strong>of</strong>plants)Potential newarabica area(ha)39,000 15,500 6,000 3,000 6,000 15’000,000 3,300Sources: Extrapolation from PAB figures and 2007 producers’ survey consider<strong>in</strong>g a total number <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee produc<strong>in</strong>g villages <strong>in</strong> theBoloven Plateau <strong>of</strong> 125 for a total number <strong>of</strong> 15,300 households.By extrapolat<strong>in</strong>g the results observed <strong>in</strong> 400 households <strong>in</strong>terviewed <strong>in</strong> 20 villages dur<strong>in</strong>g 2007 producers’survey, we see that arabica went from very small surfaces made <strong>of</strong> residual Typica trees to 6,000 ha <strong>in</strong> lessthan 20 years. Besides, this strong plant<strong>in</strong>g dynamic seems to be ongo<strong>in</strong>g as there are further 6,000 ha thatwill become productive with<strong>in</strong> the next two years. F<strong>in</strong>ally, we observe that there is still a plant<strong>in</strong>gdynamic illustrated by the number <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee trees <strong>in</strong> farmers’ nurseries that will allow the plant<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong>further 3,300 ha with<strong>in</strong> the next years.Total c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s climbed up from around 20,000 ha to more than40,000 <strong>in</strong> 10 years. In the same time, the share <strong>of</strong> arabica passed from less than1% to 13% <strong>of</strong> total surfaces.Eventually, we must add the impact <strong>of</strong> commercial plantations as they play a role <strong>in</strong> this recent plant<strong>in</strong>gdynamic. Indeed, private <strong>in</strong>vestors have been sett<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee plantations <strong>in</strong> land concessions granted bylocal authorities. This specific issue will be discussed later on (see paragraph 5.1.2.2 <strong>in</strong> page 41).<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 23


3. Relations with <strong>in</strong>ternational economy3.1. Relations between <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector and <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee market<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee and <strong>in</strong>ternational market dynamicsWith a current annual output that oscillated between 10,000 and 20,000 MT <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> the pastthree years (80% <strong>of</strong> which is robusta), <strong>Lao</strong>s is a very small producer on the world scale as its productionstands for less than 0.2% <strong>of</strong> world c<strong>of</strong>fee production. In comparison, neighbor Vietnam, a major robustaproduc<strong>in</strong>g country exports around 800,000 MT/year 12 and has become the second world’s c<strong>of</strong>fee export<strong>in</strong>gcountry. Other important robusta produc<strong>in</strong>g countries are Indonesia (300,000 MT), Uganda (130,000 MT),Ivory Coast (130,000 MT), Cameroon (45,000 MT) and Thailand (30,000 MT).Figure 2: <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exports (MT) (1995 – 2007)2500020000Total Robusta Arabica150001000050000199519961997199819992000200120022003200420052006June-07Source: Figures from the <strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee AssociationTwo ma<strong>in</strong> patterns have affected the <strong>in</strong>ternational market <strong>of</strong> robusta c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> the last years: first <strong>of</strong> all aglobal <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> robusta share <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee market (see Figure 3 <strong>in</strong> page 25) and secondly aspectacular <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> the share <strong>of</strong> robusta from Asian produc<strong>in</strong>g countries ma<strong>in</strong>ly due to the spectacular<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> Vietnamese exports (see Table 7).Table 7: C<strong>of</strong>fee area and exports <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> robusta produc<strong>in</strong>g countries1990 1994 1998 2002 2006Area(ha)Exports(MT)Area(ha)Exports(MT)Area(ha)Exports(MT)Area(ha)Exports(MT)Area(ha)Exports(MT)Cameroon 300,000 156,676 250,000 32,753 300,000 44,743 140,000 38,381 230,000 44,385Ivory Coast 1’323,900 256,971 800,000 146,639 883,279 261,917 520,000 195,192 480,000 135,029Indonesia 746,759 414,194 797,000 276,278 844,172 335,882 1’372,184 257,150 1’263,606 317,466<strong>Lao</strong>s* 17,066 5,880 20,021 9,000 28,640 14,096 36,624 13,330 43,140 6,877 13Thailand 60,320 60,086 69,920 68,163 65,027 46,682 67,000 15,198 68,780 28,518Togo 21,000 14,330 45,000 9,948 48,200 9,948 48,200 6,011 34,000 7,074Uganda 270,000 141,161 263,000 202,126 265,000 197,161 217,504 201,471 220,000 130,373Vietnam 61,857 68,714 106,300 163,255 213,802 388,003 470,000 706,282 488,600 834,282Sources: ICO (*for <strong>Lao</strong>s, figures come from the <strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee Association)12 All figures quoted <strong>in</strong>clude robusta and arabica. However, all countries named are ma<strong>in</strong>ly robusta producers.13 After hav<strong>in</strong>g reached a historical record <strong>of</strong> 23,000 MT <strong>in</strong> 2004, <strong>Lao</strong> exports dramatically dropped <strong>in</strong> 2005 and 2006 due to droughtepisodes and CBB (c<strong>of</strong>fee berry borer) attacks. Exports have considerably recovered <strong>in</strong> 2007. For <strong>in</strong>stance <strong>in</strong> July 2007, more than18,000 MT <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee have already been exported accord<strong>in</strong>g to the <strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee Association.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 24


As regards regional disparities among major robusta produc<strong>in</strong>g countries, we observe that exports havestagnated or even dropped <strong>in</strong> the past 15 years <strong>in</strong> most African countries which are traditional robustaexporters. In the same time, most Asian countries have considerably <strong>in</strong>creased their surfaces and exports(see Table 7 <strong>in</strong> page 24). One <strong>of</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> reasons <strong>of</strong> this dynamic is the devaluation <strong>of</strong> most Asiancurrencies follow<strong>in</strong>g the crisis <strong>of</strong> 1997 as this exchange rate policy generally boosts countries’ exports(c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong>ternational prices are <strong>in</strong> US dollars). We observe the same trends concern<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces as <strong>in</strong>most African robusta produc<strong>in</strong>g countries surfaces have stagnated or decreased <strong>in</strong> comparison to their1990 level whereas <strong>in</strong> most Asian countries c<strong>of</strong>fee areas have spectacularly <strong>in</strong>creased; they have beenmultiplied by 8 <strong>in</strong> Vietnam, by 1.7 <strong>in</strong> Indonesia and have more than doubled <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s.As regards the relative <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> robusta share <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ternational market shown <strong>in</strong> Figure 3, the globaltrend (the share <strong>of</strong> robusta went from 25% to 40% <strong>in</strong> 20 years) appears contradictory with the commonlyaccepted idea that c<strong>of</strong>fee market should be governed by quality demand s<strong>in</strong>ce the dismantlement <strong>of</strong>quotas policy <strong>in</strong> 1989. In fact, there has been an <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g demand for low-price c<strong>of</strong>fee with low qualitystandards for the needs <strong>of</strong> down-market c<strong>of</strong>fee products segment, collective cater<strong>in</strong>g, c<strong>of</strong>fee mach<strong>in</strong>es,<strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fees, etc. These markets generally use robusta c<strong>of</strong>fee.Figure 3: Share <strong>of</strong> robusta <strong>in</strong> world c<strong>of</strong>fee production (1969-2003)Source: Daviron and Ponte (2005)In such scope, <strong>Lao</strong> robusta turns out to be very attractive for <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee buyers as they can buy itat a quite low price (there are not quality standards and there is a price penalty for <strong>Lao</strong> orig<strong>in</strong>) and it hascerta<strong>in</strong> organoleptic qualities (<strong>Lao</strong> robusta is strong and balanced which makes it <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> themak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee blends as a taste balancer).Remark: There is a gap between export and production statistics. Indeed, when we compare Figure 1 and Figure 2 weobserve a great difference between exports and production that cannot be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by domestic consumption. Thereason is that production is calculated by national authorities based on field estimations whereas exports arecalculated by the exporters’ association (LCA) based on exporters’ <strong>in</strong>voices. In the first case, local authorities lack themeans to carry out proper statistics and rely on second-hand <strong>in</strong>formation. In the second case the reliability <strong>of</strong> thedata depends on the accuracy <strong>of</strong> the figures lent by export<strong>in</strong>g companies.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee and <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee pricesThe prices <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee depend entirely on the <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee prices (as <strong>Lao</strong>s doesn’t have anypower <strong>of</strong> negotiation because <strong>of</strong> its small production and doesn’t belong to any <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee body).The price <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> robusta is fixed accord<strong>in</strong>g to the robusta <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee price (<strong>in</strong> London) whereas<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 25


the price <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> arabica is decided accord<strong>in</strong>g to the price <strong>of</strong> “other arabica milds” <strong>in</strong> the New Yorkmarket 14 . The evolution <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee prices s<strong>in</strong>ce 1975 is shown <strong>in</strong> Annex 4 (page 81).C<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong>ternational prices are characterized by great fluctuations and the succession <strong>of</strong> crisis andexpansion periods. A first period <strong>of</strong> crisis started <strong>in</strong> 1989 (when ICO quota policies were suppressed) andended with a dramatic raise <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee prices after Brazil’s frosts <strong>in</strong> 1994. In 1999, <strong>in</strong>ternationalc<strong>of</strong>fee market entered a second period <strong>of</strong> depletion <strong>in</strong> which robusta dropped to its historical lowest prices<strong>in</strong> 2002 (the <strong>in</strong>ternational price <strong>of</strong> robusta was divided by six between 1994 and 2002).It seems that <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exports resisted well to these crisis ma<strong>in</strong>ly because <strong>of</strong> an advantageous currencyexchange policy (strong national currency devaluation). Dur<strong>in</strong>g the hardest crisis for robusta c<strong>of</strong>fee, <strong>Lao</strong>exports rema<strong>in</strong>ed still and even <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong> 2003 and 2004 (Figure 2). S<strong>in</strong>ce 2003, there has been a slightrecovery <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational prices for both arabica and robusta and <strong>in</strong> 2007 they have reached their level <strong>of</strong>the later 90’s: around 75 cents/Lb (1,653 USD/MT) for robusta and 120 cents/Lb for arabica (2,646USD/MT).Major markets for <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee is ma<strong>in</strong>ly exported to European countries like Poland, Germany, Belgium and Switzerland.Exports to neighbor Vietnam have also considerably <strong>in</strong>creased as shown <strong>in</strong> Table 8.Table 8: <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exports (MT) by import<strong>in</strong>g country (2002 – 2006)Country 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006Poland 2,014 4,521 9,345 3,599 3,199Germany 1,956 2,031 1,672 862 418Belgium 1,490 3,035 2,633 77 1,171Switzerland 1,130 967 3,295 721 0Other European countries 5,718 665 1,546 207 112Vietnam 249 621 3,423 2,326 1,183Other ASEAN countries 500 330 686 399 639USA 0 0 12 18 18Japan 115 3 6 45 14Other countries 158 648 709 324 124TOTAL 13,330 12,821 22,617 8,578 6,753Source: Exporters’ association (LCA)As we can observe, there isn’t a clear pattern for <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ternational markets as the quantitiesexported to one specific country can strongly vary from one year to another. The explanation <strong>of</strong> suchsituation comes from the organization <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee export sector. The different commercial strategies andthe competition among a bunch <strong>of</strong> importers’ local agents are determ<strong>in</strong>ant factors on the f<strong>in</strong>al markets <strong>of</strong><strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee. Moreover, most <strong>Lao</strong> exporters follow an opportunist strategy that privileges the highest bidderat the detriment <strong>of</strong> long-term commercial relations.It is very difficult to follow the path <strong>of</strong> exported c<strong>of</strong>fee. The type <strong>of</strong> buyer (<strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee traders,representatives from regional branches, local agents, etc.) and the f<strong>in</strong>al use <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee (c<strong>of</strong>fee blends,<strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fee mak<strong>in</strong>g, etc.) make it hard to follow up the products. Besides, there is a certa<strong>in</strong> lack <strong>of</strong>transparency regard<strong>in</strong>g some c<strong>of</strong>fee exports, especially those to Vietnam. Indeed, despite these exports arerecorded <strong>in</strong> the exporters’ association figures, it was impossible to <strong>in</strong>terview an exporter hav<strong>in</strong>g soldc<strong>of</strong>fee to this country <strong>in</strong> the past years.14 International c<strong>of</strong>fee prices are fixed <strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exchange markets <strong>of</strong> import<strong>in</strong>g countries (London, New York, Hamburg). They aremade by tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to account the prices <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> produc<strong>in</strong>g countries. These prices are calculated for four great categories <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee:Colombian milds, Brazilian naturals (both arabicas), other arabica milds and robustas.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 26


Another remarkable fact is that <strong>in</strong> spite <strong>of</strong> the alleged uniqueness (<strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> taste) and the great demand<strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> robusta, c<strong>of</strong>fee exports still suffer from a price penalty <strong>of</strong> 100 to 150 USD/MT accord<strong>in</strong>g to the<strong>in</strong>ternational price (London). It seems that <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee has not managed to get rid <strong>of</strong> a certa<strong>in</strong> badreputation <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational quality standards and the reliability <strong>of</strong> its operators.In spite <strong>of</strong> its uniqueness and a high demand, <strong>Lao</strong> robusta is boughtwith a price rebate <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational market.The markets for <strong>Lao</strong> arabica are for a great part the same as for robusta 15 , excepted for the arabica sold <strong>in</strong>niche markets. Washed arabica exports started <strong>in</strong> the later 90’s as a result <strong>of</strong> the development <strong>of</strong> newplantations <strong>of</strong> the dwarf-variety. However, the first experiences <strong>of</strong> high-quality arabica for niche marketswere made with c<strong>of</strong>fee from the old variety (Typica) as the dwarf variety has a problem <strong>of</strong> bad reputation<strong>in</strong> some important markets like the United States.3.2. Trade organizationAs <strong>Lao</strong>s is a landlocked country, c<strong>of</strong>fee must be exported through another country which is generallyThailand. Paksong (the largest town <strong>of</strong> the Boloven Plateau) is only 50 Km from Pakse and less than 100Km from the Thai border (Vangtao/Chong Mek check po<strong>in</strong>t). Export scheme is the same for most <strong>Lao</strong>operators: c<strong>of</strong>fee is bagged and stock <strong>in</strong> one <strong>of</strong> exporters’ warehouse located alongside the road betweenPakse and Paksong; exporters br<strong>in</strong>g the c<strong>of</strong>fee to Chong Mek check po<strong>in</strong>t and then lend it to a Thaishipp<strong>in</strong>g company that carries out the transport until the <strong>in</strong>ternational port <strong>in</strong> Bangkok.There is no data about exports through other countries even if <strong>of</strong>ficially c<strong>of</strong>fee is exported to Vietnam (byland? by sea?). Moreover, it seems that no c<strong>of</strong>fee is exported through Cambodia.<strong>Lao</strong>s is a landlocked country. Most c<strong>of</strong>fee exports are made through Thailand (Bangkok) whichengenders high transport costs and heavy export procedures. So far there hasn’t been anyprospect<strong>in</strong>g about alternative shipp<strong>in</strong>g ways (Cambodia, Vietnam) even if big amounts <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feehave been exported to Vietnam <strong>in</strong> the past years (accord<strong>in</strong>g to LCA figures).C<strong>of</strong>fee prices structure <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s is ma<strong>in</strong>ly determ<strong>in</strong>ed by the contracts between exporters and buyers. Thestrategy <strong>of</strong> most c<strong>of</strong>fee actors ma<strong>in</strong>ly consists <strong>in</strong> seek<strong>in</strong>g pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>in</strong> the short-term, so there isn’t anyk<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> reward or special market networks for different qualities <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee.At <strong>in</strong>stitutional level, no specific <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> coord<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g organization has been set up <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s. As aconsequence, c<strong>of</strong>fee trade is <strong>in</strong> the hands <strong>of</strong> private actors (exporters, importer agents, middlemen andproducers) with a partial control <strong>of</strong> national authorities (taxes, certifications, overall control). Moreover,the geographical concentration <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee production and a quite small number <strong>of</strong> actors make that <strong>Lao</strong>c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> is shorter that <strong>in</strong> many export<strong>in</strong>g countries. For example, 50% <strong>of</strong> the green robustac<strong>of</strong>fee is sold directly to exporters by producers.3.3. Trade agreements<strong>Lao</strong>s is member <strong>of</strong> ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA) s<strong>in</strong>ce 1997 and has trade preferences from Australia,Ch<strong>in</strong>a, the European Union, Japan and Thailand as well as a bilateral trade agreement with the UnitedStates. Moreover, <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong> is negotiat<strong>in</strong>g for WTO membership and its accession is expected <strong>in</strong> 2008.As a Least Developed Country (LDC), <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong> has trade preferences from different countries and tradeblocs. There is a trade preference from Thailand, though it is not very relevant <strong>in</strong> the case <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee as verylittle amounts are exported to this country. Trade preferences from Vietnam might have a stronger impactas c<strong>of</strong>fee exports to this country are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g (see Table 8 <strong>in</strong> page 20). Besides the preferential tariffs,these agreements foresee a development <strong>of</strong> exports to Vietnam through the development <strong>of</strong>15 In fact, most arabica is bought by the same buyers than robusta<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 27


communication roads and the facilitation <strong>of</strong> cross-border transports. In the next years, c<strong>of</strong>fee exportsthrough Vietnamese ports could become an alternative to exports through Bangkok.F<strong>in</strong>ally, the most relevant trade preference agreement as regards c<strong>of</strong>fee exports is the European Union’sGeneralized System <strong>of</strong> Preference (EU-GPS) that has been applied s<strong>in</strong>ce 1999. S<strong>in</strong>ce 2002, almost allproducts from the <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong> (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g green c<strong>of</strong>fee) are eligible for duty free export to all EU countries.The only products excluded are sugar, rice and bananas.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 28


4. Relations with national economy4.1. The importance <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector <strong>in</strong> national economyAccord<strong>in</strong>g to statistics from the M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> Industry and Commerce (MIC), dur<strong>in</strong>g the fiscal year2005/2006, the amount <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exports represented 1% <strong>of</strong> the value <strong>of</strong> total <strong>Lao</strong> exports (m<strong>in</strong>erals, goldand garment represented almost 70% <strong>of</strong> total export value). However, c<strong>of</strong>fee is a major agriculturalexport-commodity for the country. In 2004/2005 it represented 16% <strong>of</strong> total agricultural exports (Table 9).Table 9: Value <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Exports 2004-2005 (USD)Total ValueExport% share <strong>of</strong> Total(<strong>of</strong>ficial and <strong>in</strong>formal data)Livestock 15’539,540 25%C<strong>of</strong>fee 9’599,327 16%NTFPs* 11’756,668 19%Other Agricultural Products 24’556,657 40%Totals 61’452,192 100%Source: Table from UNDP report on International Trade and Human Development <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong>, 2006.*Non Timber Forest ProductsAt regional level, c<strong>of</strong>fee is a first-order crop for thousands <strong>of</strong> households <strong>in</strong> the very specific area <strong>of</strong> theBoloven Plateau. By extrapolat<strong>in</strong>g the figures from PAB basel<strong>in</strong>e survey and 2007 farmers’ survey, we canestimate that c<strong>of</strong>fee represents 30 to 40% <strong>of</strong> total surface and rema<strong>in</strong>s by far the ma<strong>in</strong> crop <strong>in</strong> zones above900 m <strong>of</strong> altitude. Besides, it is by far the ma<strong>in</strong> source <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come for more than 80% <strong>of</strong> the households <strong>in</strong>this area as shown <strong>in</strong> Figure 4.Figure 4: Importance <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> households’ annual <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau33%1%14%52%Less than 10% 10% to 50%50% to 90% More than 90%In conclusion, we can affirm that c<strong>of</strong>fee is economically important forthe country (as an export commodity) and fundamental for southernprov<strong>in</strong>ces and Boloven Plateau households.4.2. C<strong>of</strong>fee domestic marketSo far, <strong>Lao</strong>s’s c<strong>of</strong>fee consumption per capita rema<strong>in</strong>s limited if compared with other countries’ level (seeTable 10). With a yearly consumption per capita <strong>of</strong> around 120 g, <strong>Lao</strong> domestic market consumes morethan thirty times less than most import<strong>in</strong>g countries and several times less that some important export<strong>in</strong>gcountries. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to our estimations, <strong>Lao</strong> domestic market uses around 600 to 800 tons <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>feeper year which stands for less than 5% <strong>of</strong> total c<strong>of</strong>fee production.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 29


Table 10: C<strong>of</strong>fee consumption (<strong>in</strong> Kg/capita/year) <strong>in</strong> some import<strong>in</strong>g and export<strong>in</strong>g countriesExport<strong>in</strong>g countriesImport<strong>in</strong>g countriesBrazil 5.15 Belgium 8.84Indonesia 0.51 F<strong>in</strong>land 11.92Ethiopia 1.44 France 5.15Mexico 0.83 Germany 6.6Colombia 1.89 Poland 3.07India 0.07 Japan 3.41Philipp<strong>in</strong>es 0.60 Switzerland 7.51<strong>Lao</strong>s* 0.12 USA 4.09Source: Newsletter from the International C<strong>of</strong>fee Association (*excepted <strong>Lao</strong>s)Nevertheless, even if no <strong>of</strong>ficial figures are available and no specific study has been carried out on thisissue, most actors agree on the fact there has been a great development <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee domestic market anddomestic c<strong>of</strong>fee consumption with<strong>in</strong> the last years. Some qualitative <strong>in</strong>dicators illustrate this recentdynamic: new roast<strong>in</strong>g companies have appeared, roast<strong>in</strong>g methods have been improved, the range <strong>of</strong>c<strong>of</strong>fee products proposed to consumers has considerably widen, roasted <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee has started to be soldabroad with a high quality image, etc.<strong>Lao</strong> domestic market is characterized by a great segmentation <strong>of</strong> its products and a strong differentiation<strong>of</strong> consumers (see also chapter 6.3 page 62). In the one hand, most <strong>Lao</strong>tians consume a beverage madefrom low quality robusta c<strong>of</strong>fee mixed with volume and flavor additives (palm sugar, butter, localalcohol, etc.). In the other hand, we observe an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> a certa<strong>in</strong> category <strong>of</strong> well-<strong>of</strong>f customers (foreignresidents, some tourist as well as a develop<strong>in</strong>g middle-upper <strong>Lao</strong> class) liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> large cities anddemand<strong>in</strong>g pure roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee (or “European style” c<strong>of</strong>fee). F<strong>in</strong>ally, there has been a great development<strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fees consumption <strong>in</strong> the past years, to such po<strong>in</strong>t that some local roast<strong>in</strong>g companies havestarted to sell their own <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fees.These new consumption behaviors as well as the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> domestic consumers’ purchas<strong>in</strong>gcapacities have engendered a segmentation <strong>of</strong> domestic market (Table 11) accord<strong>in</strong>g to the type <strong>of</strong>product, the type <strong>of</strong> consumer and the place <strong>of</strong> consumption.Table 11: Characterization <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee domestic marketType <strong>of</strong> product Places <strong>of</strong> consumption Consumer typologyLocal-style or Mixedc<strong>of</strong>feesCountrywide (markets and street spots) Occasional consumers, ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>Lao</strong>tiansEuropean style orPure roasted c<strong>of</strong>feesLarge cities: Vientiane, Luang Prabang,Pakse…Regular consumers. Ma<strong>in</strong>ly foreigners andsome <strong>Lao</strong>tiansInstant c<strong>of</strong>fees Countrywide Occasional consumers, ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>Lao</strong>tiansAs the purchas<strong>in</strong>g power <strong>of</strong> the population will grow and that new consumption habits will develop, onemight expect that c<strong>of</strong>fee domestic market will cont<strong>in</strong>ue to expand with<strong>in</strong> the next years.C<strong>of</strong>fee consumption per capita is very low <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s (120g/cap/year).However, domestic market is very dynamic and segmented.4.3. C<strong>of</strong>fee sector’s political and <strong>in</strong>stitutional frameWith the dismantlement <strong>of</strong> the State-controlled system that prevailed until the late 80’s, nationalauthorities and public <strong>in</strong>stitutions stepped out from <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector which was put <strong>in</strong> the hands <strong>of</strong>private actors. Today, even if some governmental and non-governmental entities are partially <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong>the <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>, their role <strong>of</strong>ten rema<strong>in</strong>s limited to tax collect<strong>in</strong>g and certificates delivery.Officially, c<strong>of</strong>fee sector’s policy is under the supervision <strong>of</strong> the M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Forestry(MAF) for all aspects l<strong>in</strong>ked to production and the M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> Industry and Commerce (MIC) for marketissues. As regards national c<strong>of</strong>fee policy, <strong>Lao</strong> authorities have been very active <strong>in</strong> the promotion <strong>of</strong> dwarf<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 30


varieties <strong>of</strong> arabica and the replacement <strong>of</strong> robusta through successive development projects <strong>in</strong> theBoloven Plateau (LUADP, <strong>PDR</strong>BP, FAO c<strong>of</strong>fee project and PAB).The ma<strong>in</strong> private actor 16 is <strong>in</strong>dubitably the exporters’ association (called the <strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee Association) thatgathers ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exporters and some roast<strong>in</strong>g companies. Producers have started to organize and haverecently created a second level organization called the AGPC (C<strong>of</strong>fee Producers’ Groups Association,“Association des Groupements de Producteurs de Café du Plateau des Boloven” <strong>in</strong> French) which gathersmore than 50 small producers groups. All these actors will be described <strong>in</strong> detail <strong>in</strong> sections 5, 6 and 7(from page 32 to page 73).16 LCA is under the supervision <strong>of</strong> the Chamber <strong>of</strong> Commerce, which means it depends on the M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> Commerce and Industry(MIC)<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 31


5. Ma<strong>in</strong> actors and activities <strong>of</strong> export c<strong>of</strong>fee sectorIn this section, we aim to present ma<strong>in</strong> actors <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector and more particularly primaryactors presented <strong>in</strong> general c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> scheme (Figure 5). First <strong>of</strong> all we will describe c<strong>of</strong>feeproduction <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s through the presentation <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> cropp<strong>in</strong>g systems and the ma<strong>in</strong> actors <strong>in</strong>volved,before focus<strong>in</strong>g on specific issues affect<strong>in</strong>g the productive sector. Then, we will describe all the agents<strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee trade from the first sell<strong>in</strong>g to the f<strong>in</strong>al buyer. F<strong>in</strong>ally we will describe the ma<strong>in</strong> actors <strong>of</strong>c<strong>of</strong>fee domestic market through the presentation <strong>of</strong> roast<strong>in</strong>g and retail<strong>in</strong>g activities.Figure 5: General scheme <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>in</strong> 2007 (for export c<strong>of</strong>fee)General c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> schemePrivate<strong>in</strong>vestors’plantationsIndividual farmersVillage middle-buyersFarmers’cooperativesDistrict-town wholesalersPlanter-exporters and wholesaler-exportersC<strong>of</strong>fee flowsCash flowsImporters’ local agents5.1. C<strong>of</strong>fee productionInternational c<strong>of</strong>fee traders/ Importers / RoastersSeveral factors have affected c<strong>of</strong>fee production <strong>in</strong> the past 10 years: First <strong>of</strong> all, the <strong>in</strong>troduction andextension <strong>of</strong> arabica by <strong>in</strong>dividual farmers has triggered an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> cultivated surfaces, the progressiveadoption <strong>of</strong> the wet-method technique and a progressive change <strong>of</strong> farmers’ cropp<strong>in</strong>g systems. Moreover,the arrival <strong>of</strong> private <strong>in</strong>vestors develop<strong>in</strong>g large surfaces <strong>of</strong> arabica <strong>in</strong> land concessions is start<strong>in</strong>g to havesignificant impacts not only on global c<strong>of</strong>fee production but also on aspects such as the labor availabilityissue, land pressure or local environmental impact. The last relevant factor regards some successfulexperiences <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exported to high quality niche markets by small farmers’ groups.5.1.1. Ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee cropp<strong>in</strong>g and process<strong>in</strong>g systems5.1.1.1. C. canephora cropp<strong>in</strong>g systemThe current cropp<strong>in</strong>g system <strong>of</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fea canephora was <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong> the 50’s as a replacement <strong>of</strong> formerarabica Typica cropp<strong>in</strong>g system that had been affected by a cryptogamic disease (c<strong>of</strong>fee leaf rust due toHemileia vastratix), the dismantlement <strong>of</strong> arabica commercialization network dur<strong>in</strong>g the Second WorldWar and recurrent frost episodes (Sallée, 2007). It can be def<strong>in</strong>ed as a low <strong>in</strong>tensive productive systemwith a structure <strong>of</strong> plantations (trees’ density, prun<strong>in</strong>g techniques, etc.) meant to be as low labordemand<strong>in</strong>gas possible and that allows the transit <strong>of</strong> cattle under c<strong>of</strong>fee trees (see Picture 1). Economicallyspeak<strong>in</strong>g, we can say it is a low-risk cropp<strong>in</strong>g system for farmers as it requires very little <strong>in</strong>puts <strong>in</strong> terms<strong>of</strong> workforce and <strong>in</strong>vestment.The follow<strong>in</strong>g table summarizes its ma<strong>in</strong> technical characteristics:<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 32


Table 12: Characteristics <strong>of</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fea canephora cropp<strong>in</strong>g system <strong>in</strong> the Boloven PlateauVariety (cultivar) Seeds <strong>in</strong>troduced from Africa and Vietnam <strong>in</strong> 1940-50.Age <strong>of</strong> the plantations 10 to 50 yearsType <strong>of</strong> plantsSeedl<strong>in</strong>gs harvested under exist<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee trees. Very rare tree nurseriesPrevious cultivations Long time ago, after slash and burn or as replacement <strong>of</strong> old Typica plantationsShadeNatural and heterogeneous (forest trees, fruit trees, etc.)Density <strong>of</strong> plantation Low: 900 to 2,000 trees / ha. 1,111 trees (3x3m) is the most frequent densityAssociationFruit trees, shade trees, other useful trees (for cattle feed<strong>in</strong>g and night penn<strong>in</strong>g)Free growth with regenerat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> some axes after the harvest. Very high treePrun<strong>in</strong>gstructure allow<strong>in</strong>g the passage <strong>of</strong> cattle. Great number <strong>of</strong> orthotropic axes (between5 and 30)FencesNone (cattle pass<strong>in</strong>g)- Weed<strong>in</strong>g before harvestTechnical it<strong>in</strong>erary- Harvest- Ma<strong>in</strong>tenance through cattle pass<strong>in</strong>gFertilizationNone. Otherwise through cattle pass<strong>in</strong>g and night penn<strong>in</strong>gType <strong>of</strong> systemLow <strong>in</strong>tensive “pick<strong>in</strong>g” systemAnnual labor out harvest About 50 DW for weed<strong>in</strong>gYieldsFrom 100 to 600 kg <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee/ha follow<strong>in</strong>g the altitude and the year (strongbiannual variability)System’s current dynamic Under replacement (by arabica) <strong>in</strong> the uplands (<strong>in</strong> altitudes above 900m)DW=Days-worker (one day <strong>of</strong> work carried out by one worker)Picture 1 : Robusta plantation with cattleFigure 6: Robusta yields <strong>in</strong> 2007 (households’ distribution ranges)Nb <strong>of</strong>households160140120100806040200Less than300300 to 600 600 to 900 900 to1200More than1200Robusta yields (<strong>in</strong> Kg <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee/ha)Average: 517 Kg, Median: 420 KgSample size: 380<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 33


Remark: 2007 was an exceptional year (follow<strong>in</strong>g two years with very low yields). The actual average yield should bearound 300 kg <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee/ha.The robusta cropp<strong>in</strong>g system is the most widely spread <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau. It is carried out <strong>in</strong>altitudes between 400 and 1400 m. Its bottom limit is around 700m, as under this altitude robusta trees areheavily affected by the length <strong>of</strong> the dry season (flower abortion). Above 1200 m, the risks <strong>of</strong> frost are veryhigh.Robusta cropp<strong>in</strong>g system is the most widespread <strong>in</strong> Boloven Plateau. It is anon <strong>in</strong>tensive system, without chemical <strong>in</strong>put, adapted to divagation system <strong>of</strong>cattle. It is also an economically non risky system.By extrapolat<strong>in</strong>g the data from producers’ survey we can estimate that this cropp<strong>in</strong>g system is carried out<strong>in</strong> around 90% <strong>of</strong> the farms (the percentage would be around 40% for arabica).5.1.1.2. Arabica cropp<strong>in</strong>g systemsTable 13: Characteristics <strong>of</strong> arabica cropp<strong>in</strong>g system <strong>in</strong> the Boloven PlateauTypica system“Dwarf variety” systemVariety (cultivar) Typica Catimor (l<strong>in</strong>es from Portugal and Costa Rica)Age <strong>of</strong> plantations More than 50 years Less than 15 yearsType <strong>of</strong> plantsSeedl<strong>in</strong>gs picked under exist<strong>in</strong>g Seeds (from a research centre or exist<strong>in</strong>g plantations)c<strong>of</strong>fee trees. Rarely with nurseries. and nursery <strong>in</strong> plastic bagsPrevious cultivation After slash and burn system Generally <strong>in</strong>side old robusta plantationsDensity <strong>of</strong>plantationLow 900 to 1,200 trees per ha. 1,111trees (3x3m) is the most frequentHigh <strong>in</strong> general 2 x 1 m, 5,000 c<strong>of</strong>fee trees/haPlantationOld. Without visible l<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g.Agro-forest type.High trees with multiples trunks.Homogenous with l<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and stak<strong>in</strong>g well markedl<strong>in</strong>es.One/two trunk(s) dwarf shrubs.Association Fruit trees and shade trees Vegetables, rice, annual crops at young stageShade Residual trees from slash/burn Erytr<strong>in</strong> trees (10 x 10) as well as other legum<strong>in</strong>ous.Prun<strong>in</strong>gFree growth with regeneration <strong>of</strong> Top prun<strong>in</strong>g and regeneration (technique <strong>in</strong> processsome axes after the harvest<strong>of</strong> assimilation, not fully adopted yet)Fences None Fence to prevent from animal entrance (cattle)Technical it<strong>in</strong>erary- Weed<strong>in</strong>g before harvest- Harvest- Ma<strong>in</strong>tenance through cattlepass<strong>in</strong>gFarmers’ system and commercial plantations- 2-3 weed<strong>in</strong>g/year (specially at young stages)- Some mulch<strong>in</strong>g and organic fertilizer (ma<strong>in</strong>lycattle manure and c<strong>of</strong>fee pulp)- Prun<strong>in</strong>g- Harvest- Sanitary pick<strong>in</strong>g after harvest (for CBB control)- Replacement (nurseries)Commercial plantations only- Chemical fertilizers- CBB chemical controlFertilization Cattle pass<strong>in</strong>g and penn<strong>in</strong>g Organic or comb<strong>in</strong>ed m<strong>in</strong>eral/organicType <strong>of</strong> systemLow <strong>in</strong>tensive “pick<strong>in</strong>g” system Intensive system (variation <strong>of</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong>-Americansystems)Annual labor out About 30DW for weed<strong>in</strong>gAbout 110 DW/haharvestYield < 150 kg <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee/ha 600 to 1,500 kg <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee/haUnder elim<strong>in</strong>ation andSystem’s dynamic replacement. Subsistence due toJCFC and Oxfam groups marketsCBB: C<strong>of</strong>fee Berry Borer (Hypothenemus hampei)DW= Days-workerOn rapid <strong>in</strong>crease. The area should <strong>in</strong>crease by threefold<strong>in</strong> the next five years<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 34


There are two different cropp<strong>in</strong>g systems for arabica <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau depend<strong>in</strong>g on the variety: the“Typica” cropp<strong>in</strong>g system and the newly <strong>in</strong>troduced “dwarf variety” cropp<strong>in</strong>g system (referr<strong>in</strong>g to theCatimor variety). The “dwarf system” was <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong> early 90’s <strong>in</strong> the scope <strong>of</strong> development projects(especially LUADP and <strong>PDR</strong>PB) and has been steadily develop<strong>in</strong>g ever s<strong>in</strong>ce (even replac<strong>in</strong>g some oldTypica and C. canephora plantations). The “Typica” cropp<strong>in</strong>g system is a remnant <strong>of</strong> old colonial system(set between 1920 and 1950). Currently, this system is <strong>in</strong> decrease.Picture 2: Arabica plantation (dwarf variety cropp<strong>in</strong>g system)Arabica Typica cropp<strong>in</strong>g system is “semi abandoned”.Arabica Catimor cropp<strong>in</strong>g system has been well adopted by producers and is rapidly spread<strong>in</strong>g.It is an <strong>in</strong>tensive system very high-demand<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> labor and fertilization.Around half <strong>of</strong> arabica surfaces aren’t productive yet, besides, many farmers have nurseries with arabicatrees (ma<strong>in</strong>ly Catimor). For <strong>in</strong>stance, among the total arabica surface <strong>in</strong> our study’s sample (around 400ha), only 50% is productive. In the same sample, the number <strong>of</strong> arabica trees <strong>in</strong> the nurseries would allowthe plant<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> further 170 ha (which represents a potential <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> 42%).Figure 7: Arabica yields <strong>in</strong> 2007 (households’ distribution ranges)Nb <strong>of</strong>households9080706050403020100Less than300300 to 600 600 to 900 900 to1200More than1200Arabica yields * (<strong>in</strong> Kg <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee/ha)Average 573 Kg, Median:433,5 KgSample size: 216* Includ<strong>in</strong>g both Typica and Catimor varietiesThis graphic is typical <strong>of</strong> young plantations that are just start<strong>in</strong>g to produce. The column “less than 300Kg” represents young Catimor plantations (dur<strong>in</strong>g their first year <strong>of</strong> production) and the old Typicacropp<strong>in</strong>g system. In a few years, we should observe two clearly different columns represent<strong>in</strong>g the twocropp<strong>in</strong>g systems. The average yield for adult Catimor plantations should range from 800 to 1,000 Kg <strong>of</strong>green c<strong>of</strong>fee/ha.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 35


5.1.1.3. Dry method process (for C. canephora)In <strong>Lao</strong>s, almost all robusta c<strong>of</strong>fee is processed through the dry method (Table 14). A complete absence <strong>of</strong>quality standards at export level (which is reflected at production level) makes the farmers take very littlecare dur<strong>in</strong>g harvest (one or two harvest rounds versus three to five for arabica) and at all stages <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeprocess<strong>in</strong>g, especially dur<strong>in</strong>g cherries’ dry<strong>in</strong>g (<strong>in</strong> many cases cherries are dried on the bare ground wherethey are <strong>in</strong> contact with animals, excrements, etc). One <strong>of</strong> the causes is the absence <strong>of</strong> a real qualityremunerationsystem (farmers get the same price whatever the quality <strong>of</strong> their c<strong>of</strong>fee is, except penaltiesfor very bad c<strong>of</strong>fees).Farmers have the possibility to sell either dried-cherries or unsorted green c<strong>of</strong>fee (after hull<strong>in</strong>g). In mostcases, dried-cherries are hulled <strong>in</strong> modified rice hullers, <strong>in</strong> small workshops belong<strong>in</strong>g to another villager(generally a village buyer). All wholesalers and export<strong>in</strong>g companies have also modified rice huller orspecific c<strong>of</strong>fee hullers for dried-cherries transformation.Table 14: Robusta c<strong>of</strong>fee dry-process <strong>in</strong> the Boloven PlateauOperation Product obta<strong>in</strong>ed Theoretical yieldReception 30-50% <strong>of</strong> red cherries 100 kgDry<strong>in</strong>g on the bare ground,tarpaul<strong>in</strong>s, tables or concrete areas.15-23 % HR dried-cherries42 kg (if 12% HR which is the<strong>in</strong>ternational standard)Hull<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> modified rice-huller 15-20% HR green c<strong>of</strong>fee 22 kg (if 12% HR)HR= Humidity ratePicture 3: Robusta cherries dry<strong>in</strong>g on bare groundPicture 4: Robusta cherries dry<strong>in</strong>g on tarpaul<strong>in</strong><strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 36


Picture 5: Village modified c<strong>of</strong>fee hullerPicture 6: Industrial hullers (Dao Heuang company)Quality control is very rough and generally subjective. In most cases, c<strong>of</strong>fee buyers just check the globalquality through simple observation or by us<strong>in</strong>g very empirical methods (bit<strong>in</strong>g, shak<strong>in</strong>g, etc.). If theproduct doesn’t satisfy some basic criteria (especially humidity) buyers give price penalties. The scale <strong>of</strong>such penalties is also subjective and can reach 20% <strong>of</strong> the total value <strong>of</strong> the product.Robusta post-harvest process is the dry-method, careless about the quality:dry<strong>in</strong>g cherries on the bare ground is very common; the quality controlsystem set by buyers is light, subjective and engenders penalties toproducers. Producers sell both dried-cherries and unsorted green c<strong>of</strong>fee.5.1.1.4. Wet method process (ma<strong>in</strong>ly for arabica)Arabica c<strong>of</strong>fee is almost exclusively processed through the wet method follow<strong>in</strong>g a technical scheme<strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong> the 1990’s by the <strong>PDR</strong>PB project and adopted ever s<strong>in</strong>ce by most producers. Producersma<strong>in</strong>ly process their c<strong>of</strong>fee with little manual pulpers (<strong>in</strong> some cases motorized), ferment and wash it <strong>in</strong>plastic buckets before dry<strong>in</strong>g it on tables or racks. The only variation brought <strong>in</strong> the early 2000 was thesubstitution <strong>of</strong> the natural fermentation by a mechanical demucilag<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g. The ma<strong>in</strong> difference between<strong>Lao</strong> standards and most export<strong>in</strong>g countries’ standards (for washed c<strong>of</strong>fee) is that <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s beans aren’tsorted after the pulp<strong>in</strong>g. Some robusta c<strong>of</strong>fee has been processed through this system on very specificexport demands. Samples processed <strong>in</strong> 2006 and 2007 demonstrated unique and very orig<strong>in</strong>al tastecharacteristics.Table 15: Wet process system <strong>in</strong> the Boloven PlateauOperation Product obta<strong>in</strong>ed Theoretical yieldReception 95% <strong>of</strong> red cherries 100 kgSelection by float<strong>in</strong>g First quality red cherries 97 kgMechanical pulp<strong>in</strong>g Humid parchment with mucilage 54 kgFermentation or mechanical demucilag<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g. Humid parchment c<strong>of</strong>fee 45 kgWash<strong>in</strong>g Washed humid parchment c<strong>of</strong>fee 45 kgDry<strong>in</strong>g on racks Dry parchment c<strong>of</strong>fee (12-15% HR) 23 kgFarmers have the choice between red cherries and parchment sell<strong>in</strong>g, depend<strong>in</strong>g on their transformationcapacity. Today, many farmers can only sell cherries as they lack the means and <strong>in</strong>frastructures to carryout the wet-process. The type <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sold also depends on the moment dur<strong>in</strong>g harvest<strong>in</strong>g period. At thebeg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g and at the end <strong>of</strong> harvest<strong>in</strong>g period, when the amounts <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee harvested are very small,farmers will rather sell cherries (great need <strong>of</strong> cash at the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> the harvest for current expensesand labor pay<strong>in</strong>g).Picture 7: Reception and weigh<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> red cherriesPicture 8: Arabica cherries pulp<strong>in</strong>g<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 37


Picture 9: Wash<strong>in</strong>g and density grad<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> arabicaparchment <strong>in</strong> the wash<strong>in</strong>g canalPicture 10: Dry<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> arabica parchment <strong>in</strong> traysThere is a l<strong>in</strong>k between the f<strong>in</strong>al quality <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee and the wet-method process. Indeed, the f<strong>in</strong>al quality <strong>of</strong>c<strong>of</strong>fee depends for a great part on the percentage <strong>of</strong> red cherries dur<strong>in</strong>g the harvest and process<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>feethrough the wet method compels to a meticulous harvest <strong>in</strong> which only ripe red cherries are picked(selective pick<strong>in</strong>g) as green cherries cannot be pulped easily. When producers only sell cherries, thepercentage <strong>of</strong> green cherries is higher.Arabica post-harvest process is the wet-method with good care <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee quality.It has been recently adopted by producers without any problem <strong>of</strong> adaptation.Today, the ma<strong>in</strong> limit<strong>in</strong>g factor is farmers’ process<strong>in</strong>g capacity (f<strong>in</strong>ancialcapability to build either <strong>in</strong>dividual or collective wet-mills).5.1.2. C<strong>of</strong>fee producers’ typology5.1.2.1. Individual farmersIndividual farmers are the ma<strong>in</strong> actors <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee primary production (despite the rapid development <strong>of</strong>commercial c<strong>of</strong>fee plantations). It was difficult to estimate the actual number <strong>of</strong> households produc<strong>in</strong>gc<strong>of</strong>fee. In 2002 Duris et al. estimated to 27,000 the number <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee producer households <strong>in</strong> the BolovenPlateau. By extrapolat<strong>in</strong>g the figures from PAB project village basel<strong>in</strong>e data as well as figures from 2007producers’ survey we estimated the total number <strong>of</strong> households produc<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee to around 15,000 (for atotal number <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee produc<strong>in</strong>g villages <strong>of</strong> 125). We estimate that <strong>in</strong>dividual farmers cultivate more than90% <strong>of</strong> total c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces, which stands for more than 42,000 ha.There are around 15,000 households that produce c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> the BolovenPlateau. They cultivate more than 40,000 ha.In the scope <strong>of</strong> this study, a specific farmer survey was carried out between May and August 2007 with400 households <strong>of</strong> 20 villages. Villages were randomly selected among the 51 villages supported by PABproject <strong>in</strong> Paksong and <strong>Lao</strong>ngam districts (see Annex 5 <strong>in</strong> page 82). Inside each village, 20 householdswere also randomly selected. Household questionnaires dealt with issues such as household’scharacteristics, c<strong>of</strong>fee production, first c<strong>of</strong>fee sell<strong>in</strong>g and labor issues. At the end <strong>of</strong> the survey, acomprehensive statistic database was compiled.Remark: Villages were chosen among PAB supported villages for material and logistic reasons (facility <strong>of</strong> transport,presence <strong>of</strong> technical staff, villagers’ trust). However, this might have brought some bias to the sample for thefollow<strong>in</strong>g reasons:<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 38


- PAB villages were selected by district authorities accord<strong>in</strong>g to their own development criteria.- Most PAB villages are located <strong>in</strong> high altitudes.As a consequence, there might be a bias regard<strong>in</strong>g the share <strong>of</strong> arabica (as there is a government promotion policy <strong>in</strong>highland villages), the proportion <strong>of</strong> villages sell<strong>in</strong>g high quality c<strong>of</strong>fee (ma<strong>in</strong>ly located <strong>in</strong> that area) and thedevelopment <strong>of</strong> livestock (as it is one <strong>of</strong> the activities <strong>of</strong> PAB project).Based on the <strong>analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> this database, available bibliography and relevant <strong>in</strong>formation brought from thefield, we established a c<strong>of</strong>fee producers’ typology. Relevant criteria such as the altitude, the importance <strong>of</strong>c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> households’ <strong>in</strong>come or households’ capital were taken <strong>in</strong>to account to differentiate relativelyhomogeneous categories <strong>of</strong> farmers as shown <strong>in</strong> Table 16 and Table 17.Table 16: Ma<strong>in</strong> criteria lead<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>dividual farmersʹ typologyCriteriaAltitudeTotal c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong>comeShare <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> household’s <strong>in</strong>comeLivestockPre-harvest loansTotal c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaceShare robusta/arabicaType <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sold (unprocessed,processed)Market network (ma<strong>in</strong>stream, Fairtrade,etc.)Labor (Family, external waged labor)Other cropsMeans <strong>of</strong> transportationWealth range (Poor, medium, rich)RelevanceIt determ<strong>in</strong>es the cropp<strong>in</strong>g system (possibility <strong>of</strong> arabica cultivation,livestock breed<strong>in</strong>g, rice cultivation)Expresses farmers’ wealth and <strong>in</strong>vestment capacityExpresses farmers’ dependency to c<strong>of</strong>fee.Expresses farmers’ sav<strong>in</strong>g capacity and wealthExpresses farmers’ debt rateExpresses farmers’ productive capacityExpresses farmers’ strategy, diversification and <strong>in</strong>vestment capacityExpresses farmers’ transformation and market<strong>in</strong>g capacityExpresses farmers’ market<strong>in</strong>g capacityExpresses farmers’ activity and cash flow capacityExpresses farmers’ diversificationExpresses farmers’ wealth and market<strong>in</strong>g capacityExpresses farmers’ social status (this qualification is set by authoritiesbased on their own criteria)Based on these criteria, five ma<strong>in</strong> typology groups could be identified:- A first group <strong>of</strong> large-scale wealthy diversified farmers grow<strong>in</strong>g large c<strong>of</strong>fee surfaces <strong>of</strong> bothrobusta and arabica (more than 5 ha), upland rice and other crops (vegetables, fruit trees, etc.).They breed cattle (generally more than 10 animals), pigs and poultry. Many <strong>of</strong> them may haveother sources <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come: c<strong>of</strong>fee trad<strong>in</strong>g (as many have trucks), c<strong>of</strong>fee process<strong>in</strong>g (if they own ac<strong>of</strong>fee mill) or an external salary.- A second group <strong>of</strong> mid-scale diversified c<strong>of</strong>fee producers grow<strong>in</strong>g robusta and arabica <strong>in</strong>altitudes above 600 m besides other crops (vegetables, ra<strong>in</strong> fed rice, fruit trees, etc.). They mayown little livestock (few cattle and small livestock), those who have a tok-tok can sell processedc<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> Pakse.- A third group <strong>of</strong> small-scale diversified c<strong>of</strong>fee producers grow<strong>in</strong>g robusta and some arabica.Besides c<strong>of</strong>fee, these farmers develop other crops (associated or not to c<strong>of</strong>fee plantations) likevegetables, tea, fruit trees, etc. They have very little cattle and depend for a large part on c<strong>of</strong>fee.They sell both processed and unprocessed c<strong>of</strong>fee (especially arabica) depend<strong>in</strong>g on theircapability to process c<strong>of</strong>fee (either <strong>in</strong> private or collective mills). A significant percentage makespre-harvest loans.- A fourth group <strong>of</strong> small-scale non diversified farmers that depend largely on c<strong>of</strong>fee. Thesefarmers have very little livestock (generally only poultry), and have very little access to othersources <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come besides c<strong>of</strong>fee (high c<strong>of</strong>fee-dependency). A significant percentage sellsunprocessed c<strong>of</strong>fee (especially arabica cherries) and makes pre-harvest loans.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 39


- A fifth group could <strong>in</strong>clude farmers liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> lower lands (below 600 m). No specific survey wascarried out with this type <strong>of</strong> farmers as all villages selected for the survey were above 600 m.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to previous surveys (Goud, 1996), <strong>in</strong> such altitudes, farmers ma<strong>in</strong>ly cultivate ra<strong>in</strong> fedrice (<strong>in</strong> association with other crops) and banana trees. Some might cultivate little c<strong>of</strong>fee(exclusively robusta).In the scope <strong>of</strong> this study, we will focus on the four first groups as they are the ma<strong>in</strong> actors <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeproduction. Among these producers, the share <strong>of</strong> arabica <strong>in</strong> the farm<strong>in</strong>g system is one <strong>of</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong>differentiation criteria. Indeed, not only it expresses farmers’ <strong>in</strong>vestment capacity (as the sett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> newplantations requires an <strong>in</strong>vestment) it also says a lot about farmer’s strategy (as arabica is grown follow<strong>in</strong>ga completely different cropp<strong>in</strong>g system, more <strong>in</strong>tensive, labor-demand<strong>in</strong>g, etc.).The develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> arabica also implies some advantages like higher sell<strong>in</strong>g prices and farmers’ <strong>in</strong>comestagger<strong>in</strong>g (as arabica harvest period is different from robusta’s). These reasons partially expla<strong>in</strong> the boom<strong>of</strong> arabica among Boloven farmers.Table 17 summarizes the ma<strong>in</strong> characteristics <strong>of</strong> each farmer typology group accord<strong>in</strong>g to the ma<strong>in</strong>differentiation criteria.Table 17: Characterization <strong>of</strong> farmersʹ typology groupsGroupLarge-scale wealthydiversified farmersMid-scale diversifiedc<strong>of</strong>fee producersSmall-scalediversified c<strong>of</strong>feeproducersSmall-scale notdiversified c<strong>of</strong>feeproducers% <strong>of</strong> sample 10 - 15% 20 - 25% 30 - 35% 20 - 25%C<strong>of</strong>fee surface 5 - 15 ha 4 - 5 ha 1 - 3 ha 1 - 3 haRobusta 6 - 10 ha 2 - 4 ha 1 - 2 ha 1 - 2 haArabica 2 - 4 ha 1 - 2 ha 0 - 1 ha 0 - 1 haOther crops Quite diversified Diversified Diversified Not diversifiedCattle 8 to 50 animals 2 - 5 0 - 1 0 - 1Means <strong>of</strong>transportationType <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feesoldTok-tok (75% <strong>of</strong> thefarmers <strong>in</strong> the sample)Robusta unsortedgreen c<strong>of</strong>fee andarabica parchmentMotorbikes. Somehave tok-tokRobusta: bothunsorted green anddried-cherriesArabica: both cherriesand parchmentMotorbikes. Few havetok-tokRobusta: bothunsorted green anddried-cherriesArabica: mostlycherriesMotorbikes. Very fewhave tok-tokRobusta: bothunsorted green anddried-cherriesArabica: mostlycherriesSocial status Rich and medium Medium Medium and poor Medium and poorAnnual c<strong>of</strong>feegross <strong>in</strong>come 17 45 million Kip 20 million kip 10 million kip 8 million kipPre-harvestloans (% <strong>of</strong>households)30% 46% 50% 50%% <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong>households’<strong>in</strong>come(dependency)Workforce>90%(50% <strong>of</strong> the sample)Mostly externalwaged labor>90%(23% <strong>of</strong> the sample)50-90%(60% <strong>of</strong> the sample)Family and externallabor>90%(25% <strong>of</strong> the sample)50-90%(57% <strong>of</strong> the sample)Mostly family andoccasional wagedlabor dur<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>feeharvest>90%(40% <strong>of</strong> the sample)50-90%(40% <strong>of</strong> the sample)Mostly family andoccasional wagedlabor dur<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>feeharvest17 These amounts have been calculated with 2006-07 campaign which was very good for yields and prices. Average annual c<strong>of</strong>feegross <strong>in</strong>come could be lower.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 40


5.1.2.2. Private <strong>in</strong>vestorsIn the past years, a certa<strong>in</strong> number <strong>of</strong> private companies (many <strong>of</strong> them are foreign companies, ma<strong>in</strong>lyfrom Vietnam, Ch<strong>in</strong>a or Thailand) have started to develop c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> land concessions granted by localauthorities. There is a real lack <strong>of</strong> transparency regard<strong>in</strong>g this issue. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the survey, and despiteseveral <strong>in</strong>terviews with local authorities’ representatives, it wasn’t possible to establish the actualprocedure that companies must follow <strong>in</strong> order to obta<strong>in</strong> such concessions, nor was it possible to obta<strong>in</strong>accurate figures on total surfaces granted and the area effectively planted with c<strong>of</strong>fee. Indeed, localauthorities keep records on land concessions but don’t follow up what these companies effectively do onthese lands. However, accord<strong>in</strong>g to Champasak Prov<strong>in</strong>cial Agriculture Office un<strong>of</strong>ficial estimations,among the 1,800-2,000 ha <strong>of</strong> land granted up to 2007, around 1,200 ha have been planted with c<strong>of</strong>fee trees.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the same sources, the number <strong>of</strong> land concessions has been <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g every year and thesystem should cont<strong>in</strong>ue to develop <strong>in</strong> the near future, as described <strong>in</strong> a press article on Forbes website <strong>in</strong>July 2007:“Under the agreement made between the Vietnam National C<strong>of</strong>fee Corp., Dak Uy C<strong>of</strong>fee Company <strong>of</strong>Kon Tum prov<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>in</strong> Vietnam and the Champasak authorities, the jo<strong>in</strong>t venture company will rent 1,000hectares <strong>of</strong> land to grow c<strong>of</strong>fee, with the possibility <strong>of</strong> add<strong>in</strong>g between 3,000-5,000 hectares at a laterdate.…”And“Each hectare <strong>of</strong> land will yield about two tons <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee, growers said…”And“The proposed c<strong>of</strong>fee farms will provide jobs for thousands <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s laborers and develop currentlyuncultivated land.”See forbes.com/feeds/ap/2007/07/19/ap3931609.htmlRegard<strong>in</strong>g the last sentence, <strong>in</strong>terviews with local authorities and some farmers’ statements allowestablish<strong>in</strong>g that these concessions are generally allocated <strong>in</strong> forest areas located <strong>in</strong>side village limits; <strong>in</strong>most cases this land is actually secondary forest used <strong>in</strong> upland rice cropp<strong>in</strong>g rotations or old c<strong>of</strong>feeplantations. In all cases it might seem quite hasty to describe this land as “uncultivated”.With<strong>in</strong> the past years, almost 2,000 ha have been granted to private <strong>in</strong>vestors for c<strong>of</strong>feeplant<strong>in</strong>g. In the near future, further 5,000 ha might be granted.It seems that <strong>in</strong> some specific cases, villagers may receive a f<strong>in</strong>ancial compensation. However, thecommon pattern is a private negotiation <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g the companies, local authorities and the head <strong>of</strong>village. The average length <strong>of</strong> land concessions for c<strong>of</strong>fee plant<strong>in</strong>g is around 20 years.Picture 11: Commercial plantation <strong>of</strong> arabica dwarfvarietyPicture 12: Commercial plantation (external laborfacilities <strong>in</strong> the background)<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 41


The operation scheme <strong>of</strong> these private <strong>in</strong>vestors is generally the same: dur<strong>in</strong>g the early years, c<strong>of</strong>feeplant<strong>in</strong>g and the ma<strong>in</strong>tenance <strong>of</strong> plantations is done by external waged labor hired <strong>in</strong> surround<strong>in</strong>gvillages (besides their salary, employees generally have the right to develop food crops <strong>in</strong>side youngc<strong>of</strong>fee plots). When plantations become productive, the company hires a permanent team (ma<strong>in</strong>ly for thema<strong>in</strong>tenance) and cont<strong>in</strong>ues to hire many external labors dur<strong>in</strong>g workforce peaks (weed<strong>in</strong>g, harvest).Commercial plantations are driven follow<strong>in</strong>g a very <strong>in</strong>tensive cropp<strong>in</strong>g system with a high level <strong>of</strong>chemical <strong>in</strong>puts (fertilizers and pesticides). They only grow high-density dwarf arabica varieties, us<strong>in</strong>gaggressive prun<strong>in</strong>g techniques and no shade. Their objective is to obta<strong>in</strong> yields around 2 t green c<strong>of</strong>fee/ha(see article) which represents 11 to 12 ton <strong>of</strong> cherries/ha (which is three times the current average yield <strong>in</strong>farmers’ systems). Salaried technical staff is <strong>in</strong> charge <strong>of</strong> ensur<strong>in</strong>g the technical follow-up <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feegrow<strong>in</strong>g and process<strong>in</strong>g. Eventually, most companies set their own wet-method transformation unit.In the near future, this scheme is likely to develop more and more and one can only wonder about thesusta<strong>in</strong>ability <strong>of</strong> this system as well as its social, environmental and economic consequences. Indeed, onthe one hand there might be a heavy environmental and sanitary impact due to the high levels <strong>of</strong> chemical<strong>in</strong>puts <strong>of</strong> this <strong>in</strong>tensive cropp<strong>in</strong>g system <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> water quality, fertility management and humanhealth. On the other hand the great labor demand engendered by this system (especially dur<strong>in</strong>gharvest<strong>in</strong>g season).is very likely to have a very negative impact on the global workforce availability <strong>in</strong> theBoloven Plateau (as many farmers have already difficulties to f<strong>in</strong>d external labor dur<strong>in</strong>g harvest peaks) aswell as on harvest quality (more and more strip pick<strong>in</strong>g and less selective pick<strong>in</strong>g) which could eventuallyresult <strong>in</strong> a drop <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee quality (especially for arabica).For an <strong>in</strong> depth <strong>analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> harvest labor issues, please refer to paragraph 5.1.4.5.1.2.3. Producers’ organizationsAll exist<strong>in</strong>g farmers’ organizations have been created through the support <strong>of</strong> NGOs and developmentprojects (Oxfam Australia, Jhai Foundation and PAB). Generally speak<strong>in</strong>g, the f<strong>in</strong>al objective <strong>of</strong> theseprograms is to <strong>in</strong>crease and diversify farmers’ c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong>come by produc<strong>in</strong>g high quality arabica, which issold <strong>in</strong> high added-value markets like Fair-trade. At first stages, these programs focused on the export <strong>of</strong>c<strong>of</strong>fee from the old Typica variety but now they are start<strong>in</strong>g to export c<strong>of</strong>fee from the dwarf variety. Most<strong>of</strong> these experiences are quite recent (less than 10 years) so support<strong>in</strong>g organizations still undertake mostmarket<strong>in</strong>g steps such as contacts with buyers, certifications, sell<strong>in</strong>g contracts, technical follow up, qualitycontrol and even c<strong>of</strong>fee process<strong>in</strong>g, transport<strong>in</strong>g and market<strong>in</strong>g. Farmers are generally gathered <strong>in</strong>groups, which allow a better control <strong>of</strong> the product and the share <strong>of</strong> some process<strong>in</strong>g assets.Oxfam-supported producers’ groups <strong>in</strong> Ban Katouat and Ban Vang GnaoFarmers’ groups from these two villages started to sell high-quality Typica c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> the Japanese Fair-Trade market <strong>in</strong> 2004 with the support <strong>of</strong> Oxfam Australia. In Katouat 18 village for <strong>in</strong>stance, the projectstarted to support a group <strong>of</strong> 47 families <strong>in</strong> 2003. Today, there are more than 70 members. Farmers can jo<strong>in</strong>the groups on a voluntary basis, under the condition they produce arabica (Typica) and that they haveless than 3 ha <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee.In 2004, the groups exported around 5 MT to the Japanese market (the buy<strong>in</strong>g company is called AlterTrade Japan). S<strong>in</strong>ce then quantities exported slightly <strong>in</strong>crease every year:“In the project’s first year, 2004, the group sold 5,760kg <strong>of</strong> quality c<strong>of</strong>fee to Japanese company AlterTrad<strong>in</strong>g Japan (ATJ) at a price <strong>of</strong> 15,000 kip/kilo (AUD $1.95), compared to the local market price <strong>of</strong> 5,000kip/kg (AUD 65 cents). Prov<strong>in</strong>g it was no fluke, <strong>in</strong> 2005, they sold 6,770kg to ATJ at 14,000 kip/kg (AUD$1.82) for Catimor and 17,000 kip/kg (AUD $2.21) for Typica. This year, they exported 13,620kg at 20,000kip/kg (AUD $2.60) for Catimor and 24,000kip/kg (AUD $3.12) for Typica. They have also received18 Most <strong>in</strong>formation about this project come from the <strong>in</strong>terview <strong>of</strong> the president <strong>of</strong> Katouat’s group as it wasn’t possible to meet arepresentative from the support<strong>in</strong>g organization (Oxfam Australia).<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 42


<strong>in</strong>terest from S<strong>in</strong>gapore, Thailand and France and have sent samples to Australia, United States, Belgiumand Germany.”See http: www.oxfam.org.au/oxfamnews/december_2006/dignity-<strong>in</strong>-a-c<strong>of</strong>fee-cup.htmlThe Jhai C<strong>of</strong>fee Farmer Cooperative (JCFC)JCFC was created <strong>in</strong> 2004 with villages that had benefited from a development program funded by theJhai Foundation (United States) that promoted the production <strong>of</strong> high quality c<strong>of</strong>fee as a way to improvefarmers’ livelihoods. In 2007, the cooperative gathers more than 500 families from 12 villages <strong>of</strong> theBoloven Plateau. Farmers have the possibility to jo<strong>in</strong> the cooperative on a volunteer basis and under thecondition they cultivate arabica c<strong>of</strong>fee (especially Typica as <strong>in</strong> the first years the cooperative only exportedc<strong>of</strong>fee from this variety).JCFC exports high quality Fair-trade 19 arabica c<strong>of</strong>fee to the United States and France. The cooperative stillmarkets quite small amounts <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee. In 2007 they exported two conta<strong>in</strong>ers (around 36 MT) toThanksgiv<strong>in</strong>g 20 roast<strong>in</strong>g company (US) and Alter Eco (France).Farmers pulp cherries <strong>in</strong> community pulp<strong>in</strong>g mach<strong>in</strong>es and carry on the rest <strong>of</strong> the process <strong>in</strong>dividually.The whole process takes place under the supervision <strong>of</strong> JCFC staff and the farmer commits to deliver f<strong>in</strong>equality parchment c<strong>of</strong>fee to the cooperative. The cooperative sells c<strong>of</strong>fee at Fair-trade prices <strong>in</strong> the<strong>in</strong>ternational market. In 2007 Fair-trade price was around 1.26 USD/Pound (2.77 USD/Kg), <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g 5cents/Lb <strong>of</strong> Fair-trade development prime. The price paid to farmers takes <strong>in</strong>to account all productioncosts and cooperative’s function<strong>in</strong>g (staff salaries, etc.). In 2007, JCFC farmers’ prices oscillated between18,000 and 19,000 Kip/Kg <strong>of</strong> parchment (1.84 to 1.95 USD/Kg). The average price for Arabica parchmenton the ma<strong>in</strong>stream network dur<strong>in</strong>g the same period was 14,000 -16,000 Kip/Kg (1.43 to 1.64 USD/Kg).Groups <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee producers supported by PAB and the AGPC51 farmer groups have started to organize with the support <strong>of</strong> PAB project with the view <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gtheir <strong>in</strong>come through the production and commercialization <strong>of</strong> high quality c<strong>of</strong>fee as well as <strong>in</strong>comediversification through cattle breed<strong>in</strong>g (Sallée, 2007). Based on the experience <strong>of</strong> other c<strong>of</strong>fee export<strong>in</strong>gcountries, it was decided to set a pilot project <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee producers’ organization as a way to spread newprocess techniques, to promote the production <strong>of</strong> quality c<strong>of</strong>fee and to be able to produce <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>gvolumes for <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee buyers (as most members are small-scale producers). Farmers’ groups areconsolidated through the activities <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee process<strong>in</strong>g and market<strong>in</strong>g. To that matter, collective wetprocess<strong>in</strong>gunits have been set up <strong>in</strong> 31 villages <strong>in</strong> 2007 21 . The aim is to produce high-quality washedarabicathat could be sold <strong>in</strong> high-value niche markets (Fair-trade, organic, orig<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fees, etc.) with anorig<strong>in</strong> recognition.In 2007, these farmers’ groups gathered <strong>in</strong> a second level organization called the AGPC (Boloven PlateauC<strong>of</strong>fee Producers’ Groups Association) which represents around 2,700 households. The aim <strong>of</strong> thisorganization is to gather and strengthen c<strong>of</strong>fee produc<strong>in</strong>g groups so they can have an <strong>in</strong>fluence oncommercial negotiations and be able to channel potential technical and f<strong>in</strong>ancial support. Its ma<strong>in</strong> roleswill be:- To represent Boloven Plateau c<strong>of</strong>fee producers <strong>in</strong> front <strong>of</strong> national authorities, c<strong>of</strong>fee sectororganizations (<strong>in</strong>ternally and abroad) and any c<strong>of</strong>fee-related event <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s or abroad- To support all member groups <strong>in</strong> any aspect related to c<strong>of</strong>fee production- To support all member groups <strong>in</strong> any aspect related to c<strong>of</strong>fee market<strong>in</strong>g19 JCFC has a Fair Trade certification from FLO-CERT (Fair-trade Labell<strong>in</strong>g Organizations certification company)20 See http://test.thanksgiv<strong>in</strong>gc<strong>of</strong>fee.com/cafelao/<strong>in</strong>dex21 11 <strong>of</strong> these groups have already a wet-method process experience as they work with JCFC.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 43


5.1.3. Limit<strong>in</strong>g factors for c<strong>of</strong>fee productionAs shown <strong>in</strong> Table 18, c<strong>of</strong>fee production limit<strong>in</strong>g factors are either related to the improvement <strong>of</strong> currenttechnical practices such as CBB (Hypothenemus hampei (Ferrari)) control, fertility management, plantationsstructure or dry<strong>in</strong>g (see pictures below) or to the sett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> new agricultural practices l<strong>in</strong>ked to the recentdevelopment <strong>of</strong> arabica (prun<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> dwarf variety trees, shade trees management, wet process, etc.).Table 18: C<strong>of</strong>fee production limit<strong>in</strong>g factorsC<strong>of</strong>fee primaryproductionC<strong>of</strong>fee process<strong>in</strong>gCBB controlNo CBB control (for all cropp<strong>in</strong>g systems). Except <strong>in</strong> PAB villages which are test<strong>in</strong>g aCBB <strong>in</strong>tegrated management us<strong>in</strong>g, among other techniques, Brocap® traps.C<strong>of</strong>fee prun<strong>in</strong>gRobusta and Typica cropp<strong>in</strong>g systems: no prun<strong>in</strong>g or very slight.Dwarf variety cropp<strong>in</strong>g system: prun<strong>in</strong>g technique <strong>in</strong>troduced by <strong>PDR</strong>PB project isn’twell implemented yet.Fertility managementRisks <strong>of</strong> unsusta<strong>in</strong>ability as nutrients’ exports are not compensated (except for sometransfers made by cattle pass<strong>in</strong>g and penn<strong>in</strong>g). No mulch<strong>in</strong>g and problems <strong>of</strong> rootdamage due to <strong>in</strong>adequate weed<strong>in</strong>g techniques.Plantation structure (Robusta and Typica cropp<strong>in</strong>g systems)The structure <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee plantations (density, shape <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee trees, prun<strong>in</strong>g) is meant topermit cattle transit which allows a certa<strong>in</strong> fertility transfer. However, it imposes a lowdensitysystem with very high trees that make harvest<strong>in</strong>g difficult. And yet, only 17% <strong>of</strong>the farmers have cattle 22 .Shade trees prun<strong>in</strong>gIt is becom<strong>in</strong>g an issue <strong>in</strong> the dwarf variety cropp<strong>in</strong>g system as there is no managementstrategy for associated trees.Typica cropp<strong>in</strong>g system is progressively be<strong>in</strong>g abandonedHarvest<strong>in</strong>g techniquesThere is still a high percentage <strong>of</strong> unripe green cherries, black and defective cherriess<strong>in</strong>ce harvest stage. Robusta harvest on very high trees is difficult and expensive.Process<strong>in</strong>gLack <strong>of</strong> wet-method process<strong>in</strong>g capacities (wet-mills)Dry<strong>in</strong>g (see pictures below)Generally speak<strong>in</strong>g farmers lack dry<strong>in</strong>g surfaces. There is also a lack <strong>of</strong> care dur<strong>in</strong>gc<strong>of</strong>fee dry<strong>in</strong>g (ra<strong>in</strong>s, bare ground, contact with animals, etc.)Picture 13: Dry<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee cherries on the bare groundPicture 14: Good dry<strong>in</strong>g practices: handmade dry<strong>in</strong>gtables22 PAB basel<strong>in</strong>e survey and 2007 producers’ survey<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 44


5.1.4. Harvest labor issuesGenerally, <strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee, harvest represents 60 to 100% <strong>of</strong> total production costs. In <strong>Lao</strong>s, c<strong>of</strong>fee is grownfollow<strong>in</strong>g a “natural” way, with no chemical <strong>in</strong>puts. Besides, most farmers don’t have access to adequatetransformation means. We can then assume that <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s, greater higher costs are l<strong>in</strong>ked to harvestactivities (especially the remuneration <strong>of</strong> external waged labor). This is the reason why, our farmers’survey focused more particularly on harvest labor by analyz<strong>in</strong>g issues such as workforce availability,labor peaks, differences arabica/robusta, differences family labor/external labor, etc. The aim was to makethe balance <strong>of</strong> current situation and to provide a forecast <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> the issues that c<strong>of</strong>fee sector will facewith<strong>in</strong> the next years.5.1.4.1. Labor availabilityFigure 8: Percentage <strong>of</strong> external labor dur<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee harvest (<strong>in</strong> % <strong>of</strong> households <strong>in</strong>terviewed)6%10%Arabica22%Robusta16%68%0%1-25%26-50%50-100%12%6%60%0%1-25%26-50%50-100%Figure 9: C<strong>of</strong>fee harvest workforce demand (number <strong>of</strong> day-worker / ha)1%Arabica6%Robusta31%10%22%17%Less than 3030 to 6060 to 9090 to 120120 to 150More than 15013%27%4% 4% Less than 3030 to 6060 to 9090 to 12046% 120 to 150More than 15019%Number <strong>of</strong> answers:106 (sample <strong>of</strong> 200)(Average: 139.4 days, Median: 112 days)Number <strong>of</strong> answers:190 (sample <strong>of</strong> 200)(Average: 69.8 days, Median: 60 days)The issue <strong>of</strong> labor availability must be analyzed while tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to account the differences between the twoma<strong>in</strong> cropp<strong>in</strong>g systems as described <strong>in</strong> paragraphs 5.1.1.1and 5.1.1.2. First <strong>of</strong> all, these figures confirm thefact that arabica dwarf-variety cropp<strong>in</strong>g system is more workforce-demand<strong>in</strong>g than robusta. Indeed,Figure 9 shows that arabica harvest requires almost the double <strong>of</strong> days-worker per hectare compared torobusta harvest (139.4 for arabica versus 69.8 for robusta). In fact, for a high percentage <strong>of</strong> farmers (morethan 40%), arabica harvest consumes more than 120 days-worker per hectare whereas more than 50% <strong>of</strong><strong>in</strong>terviewees require less than 60 days-worker for robusta harvest. The ma<strong>in</strong> explanation comes from thedifference <strong>of</strong> harvest<strong>in</strong>g technique (strip pick<strong>in</strong>g for robusta and selective pick<strong>in</strong>g for arabica).However, when it comes to external waged labor, we observe that robusta harvest still uses more wagedlabor then arabica. Indeed, for robusta, <strong>in</strong> more than 30% <strong>of</strong> the cases external labor represents more thanhalf <strong>of</strong> total harvest labor. For arabica this percentage drops to 16%. This can be easily expla<strong>in</strong>ed by thefact that robusta surfaces are larger <strong>in</strong> most farms and there is a greater availability <strong>of</strong> workers dur<strong>in</strong>g<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 45


obusta harvest<strong>in</strong>g period. This results echo what many farmers say about arabica harvest, that it requiresmore workforce but that it is difficult to f<strong>in</strong>d external waged labor dur<strong>in</strong>g harvest<strong>in</strong>g period as it co<strong>in</strong>cideswith rice harvest <strong>in</strong> the lowlands (October to December).Arabica harvest is more workforce-demand<strong>in</strong>g than robusta. However, c<strong>of</strong>fee producersemploy more external labor for robusta harvest for two ma<strong>in</strong> reasons: robusta surfaces arelarger and there is a greater availability <strong>of</strong> labor dur<strong>in</strong>g robusta harvest period.C<strong>of</strong>fee producers have started to meet difficulties f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g external waged labor for arabicaharvest because <strong>of</strong> the competition with rice harvest <strong>in</strong> the lowlands.Even though there aren’t clear figures about the shortage <strong>of</strong> labor for arabica harvest as arabica surfacesare still quite small and farmers still manage to f<strong>in</strong>d daily workers, there are some qualitative <strong>in</strong>dicators <strong>of</strong>this potential shortage. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>terviews, many farmers compla<strong>in</strong>ed about the difficulty to f<strong>in</strong>d labordur<strong>in</strong>g arabica harvest<strong>in</strong>g period. For <strong>in</strong>stance, a c<strong>of</strong>fee producer from Maysaisomboune tells he had to goto Khone Island (more than 100 Km south <strong>of</strong> Pakse) and spend three days there to f<strong>in</strong>d workers for c<strong>of</strong>feeharvest. Farmers have other ways to motivate workers to come to the Plateau: many producers pay fortransportation, provide the food, pay bonus to good workers, etc. This is a big issue as the workconditions are not always easy (accommodation, food, low temperatures at certa<strong>in</strong> times <strong>of</strong> the day, etc.).In fact, one <strong>of</strong> the biggest problems accord<strong>in</strong>g to some farmers is that many workers from the lowlandswant to leave the Plateau when the climate gets too cold.5.1.4.2. Workforce productivityFigure 10: Harvest workforce productivity (average weight <strong>of</strong> cherries harvested / day-worker)50%40%45%37%Arabica (% <strong>of</strong> households)50%40%43%Robusta (% <strong>of</strong> households)30%20%10%15%2% 1%30%20%10%18%24%10%4%0%Less than20 Kg20 to 40 Kg 40 to 60 Kg 60 to 80 Kg more than80 Kg0%Less than20 Kg20 to 40 40 to 60 60 to 80 more than80 KgNumber <strong>of</strong> answers:106 (sample <strong>of</strong> 200)(Average: 25.2 Kg, Median: 23 Kg)Number <strong>of</strong> answers:106 (sample <strong>of</strong> 200)(Average: 38.3 Kg, Median: 35 Kg)Figure 10 shows there is a greater productivity <strong>of</strong> work for robusta harvest despite the height <strong>of</strong> the trees(38 Kg <strong>of</strong> cherries harvested/day <strong>in</strong> average versus 25 for arabica). Here aga<strong>in</strong>, the ma<strong>in</strong> explanationcomes from the harvest<strong>in</strong>g technique (the strip pick<strong>in</strong>g allows greater rapidity). Unlike <strong>Lao</strong>s, <strong>in</strong> mostproduc<strong>in</strong>g countries external workforce is paid accord<strong>in</strong>g to the weight/volume and the averageworkforce productivity is significantly higher: 50-120 Kg/day-worker for arabica harvested with selectivepick<strong>in</strong>g and 120-250 Kg/DW for strip pick<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> arabica or robusta (Brando C. <strong>in</strong> W<strong>in</strong>tgens, 2004).Figure 11: Comparison between family and external waged labor (Kg <strong>of</strong> cherries harvested / day)60Kg cherries/day5040302010ArabicaRobusta0FamilyExternal labor<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 46


Once aga<strong>in</strong> we observe the same differences regard<strong>in</strong>g work-efficiency between robusta and arabica.However, <strong>in</strong> Figure 11 we see that the average weight <strong>of</strong> arabica cherries harvested <strong>in</strong> one day is higherfor external labor. This can be easily expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the fact family workers pay more attention to selectivepick<strong>in</strong>g than temporary labor. As a matter <strong>of</strong> fact, many farmers speak about the difficulty to control thequality <strong>of</strong> the pick<strong>in</strong>g.This difficulty <strong>of</strong> control is reflected <strong>in</strong> the modes <strong>of</strong> payment. One <strong>of</strong> the specificities <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s if comparedwith other c<strong>of</strong>fee produc<strong>in</strong>g countries is that for arabica harvest, external labor is paid accord<strong>in</strong>g to thenumber <strong>of</strong> days. In most produc<strong>in</strong>g countries, labor is paid accord<strong>in</strong>g to the weight, with a strict controlon the quality <strong>of</strong> cherries ensured by the farmer. Farmers <strong>in</strong>terviewed say that if they pay external laboraccord<strong>in</strong>g to the weight, the pick<strong>in</strong>g is not careful and that there are significant loses on the ground. Manyfarmers believe that pay<strong>in</strong>g by day motivates external labor to work thoroughly and allows greater laborflexibility.Work-efficiency is higher for robusta harvest (strip pick<strong>in</strong>g) as arabica harvest requires more care anddexterity (selective pick<strong>in</strong>g). Today, most harvest work is carried out by family workforce (Figure 8)with a greater care <strong>of</strong> the quality <strong>of</strong> harvest (Figure 11). In the next years, with the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> arabicasurfaces, farmers will have to use more and more external waged labor for arabica harvest. They mightface two ma<strong>in</strong> issues: global labor availability and harvest quality control.Besides, most farmers pay monthly wages for robusta harvest. For arabica harvest they prefer to pay dailyor weekly wages. There are two reasons to expla<strong>in</strong> this difference: <strong>in</strong> the one hand, arabica production isstill quite small and can be completed with<strong>in</strong> few days <strong>in</strong> youngest plantations. On the other hand, it is away to control the quality <strong>of</strong> the harvest as farmers can control more closely the quality <strong>of</strong> the pick<strong>in</strong>g.5.1.4.3. Future prospects on harvest labor issuesIn order to forecast the needs <strong>of</strong> external labor for c<strong>of</strong>fee harvest <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau with<strong>in</strong> the nextyears, we decided to focus on the real bottleneck, that is to say the labor for arabica harvest. Consider<strong>in</strong>gthe current productive situation (refer to Table 6 <strong>in</strong> page 23) and the expansion dynamic <strong>of</strong> commercialplantations (paragraph 5.1.2.2), we obta<strong>in</strong>ed an estimation <strong>of</strong> arabica cherry production <strong>of</strong> around 60,000MT <strong>in</strong> 2012 as shown <strong>in</strong> Table 19.Table 19: Forecast <strong>of</strong> arabica production <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau <strong>in</strong> 2009 and 2012Individual farmers’ arabica surface <strong>in</strong>production (ha)2007 2009 20125,500 11,000(estimation)15,000(estimation)Commercial plantations (estimations <strong>in</strong> ha*) 500 1,000 5,000Total productive arabica surface (ha) 6,000 12,000 20,000Total arabica production (MT <strong>of</strong> cherries) 15,000 36,000* 60,000** Estimations consider<strong>in</strong>g the current dynamic and land concession plan with Vietnamese companies** Consider<strong>in</strong>g an average yield <strong>of</strong> 3 MT <strong>of</strong> cherries/haConsider<strong>in</strong>g that, we made an estimation <strong>of</strong> global workforce needs for arabica harvest <strong>in</strong> the next 5 years:Table 20: Estimation <strong>of</strong> global workforce needs for arabica harvest <strong>in</strong> 2009 and 20122007 2009 2012Total arabica cherries production (MT) 15,000 36,000 60,000Theoretical total number <strong>of</strong> days-worker required for arabica harvest* 375,000 900,000 1’500,000Theoretical number <strong>of</strong> days-worker required per day <strong>of</strong> harvest(consider<strong>in</strong>g an average length <strong>of</strong> harvest period <strong>of</strong> 60 days)6,250 15,000 25,000Theoretical number <strong>of</strong> days-worker required per day <strong>of</strong> harvest consider<strong>in</strong>gthe harvest peak (5% <strong>of</strong> the cherries are harvested <strong>in</strong> one s<strong>in</strong>gle day)18,750 45,000 75,000* Consider<strong>in</strong>g the average weight <strong>of</strong> cherries picked by one person <strong>in</strong> one day is 40 Kg<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 47


We f<strong>in</strong>d that <strong>in</strong> 2012, arabica harvest will require an availability <strong>of</strong> more than 75,000 workers per daydur<strong>in</strong>g harvest peak which is 4 times the current workforce demand. If we consider surface <strong>in</strong>creaseestimations, commercial plantations will use around 25% <strong>of</strong> this workforce. We can already foresee some<strong>of</strong> the possible consequences <strong>of</strong> such evolution:• First <strong>of</strong> all, the price <strong>of</strong> workforce is likely to <strong>in</strong>crease because <strong>of</strong> the high demand dur<strong>in</strong>g thisperiod. In the same time, there is a risk that the pool <strong>of</strong> local labor cannot meet such demand.• The lack <strong>of</strong> workforce might modify the terms between employers and employees: paymentaccord<strong>in</strong>g to the weight, lower harvest quality requirements, more strip pick<strong>in</strong>g, etc.In 2012, global workforce demand for arabica harvest will be fourtimes higher than today.This evolution is very likely to be prejudicial to c<strong>of</strong>fee producers as itwill surely <strong>in</strong>crease their production costs and will have a negativeimpact on f<strong>in</strong>al harvest quality.5.2. C<strong>of</strong>fee commercialization (export circuit)5.2.1. Village buyers and c<strong>of</strong>fee collectorsThese two categories <strong>of</strong> agents are generally farmers (many are c<strong>of</strong>fee growers) that purchase c<strong>of</strong>fee fromother farmers liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> their village or from other surround<strong>in</strong>g villages. Their ma<strong>in</strong> strength is the deepknowledge <strong>of</strong> farmers and their direct contact with c<strong>of</strong>fee production; this is the reason why manywholesalers and export<strong>in</strong>g companies charge them <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong>.In the scope <strong>of</strong> this study, 21 middle-buyers from 10 villages were <strong>in</strong>terviewed. Most <strong>of</strong> them were c<strong>of</strong>feeplanters and some have been c<strong>of</strong>fee buyers for more than ten years. Among the 21 buyers, only 3 werecompletely <strong>in</strong>dependent whereas the other 18 were l<strong>in</strong>ked to a wholesaler/exporter.Most middle buyers purchase unprocessed c<strong>of</strong>fee from farmers (arabica cherries and robusta driedcherries) <strong>in</strong> quantities go<strong>in</strong>g from 1 up to 100 tons. They generally have dry<strong>in</strong>g areas, c<strong>of</strong>fee pulp<strong>in</strong>gmach<strong>in</strong>es, mills, etc. Thus they are able to process c<strong>of</strong>fee beans and sell processed c<strong>of</strong>fee to wholesalersand exporters.Besides c<strong>of</strong>fee purchas<strong>in</strong>g, village buyers are generally <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal credit through usury creditand pre-harvest loans. This specific issue will be presented later on <strong>in</strong> paragraph 7.2.5.2.2. Wholesalers from Pakse and <strong>Lao</strong>ngam districtsThere are around 5 wholesalers <strong>in</strong> Paksong and 2 to 3 <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>ngam. In most cases, they buy and selldifferent agricultural products with a high preem<strong>in</strong>ence <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee. In some cases they have c<strong>of</strong>feeplantations <strong>of</strong> their own. In fact, many <strong>of</strong> them are former village buyers that specialized <strong>in</strong> trade but kepta close l<strong>in</strong>k with producers <strong>in</strong> the field.Generally their range <strong>of</strong> action <strong>in</strong>cludes 30 to 50 villages with<strong>in</strong> the limits <strong>of</strong> the district. In most casesfarmers br<strong>in</strong>g their harvest to the warehouse; however wholesalers also collect some <strong>of</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee directlyfrom the farms with their own trucks. Ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sellers are <strong>in</strong>dividual farmers even if <strong>in</strong> some caseswholesalers buy c<strong>of</strong>fee from collectors and village buyers. Most transactions are carried out based onsimple verbal agreements as no contracts are set.Besides c<strong>of</strong>fee buy<strong>in</strong>g, most wholesalers provide credit services to farmers through cash or rice loans,either follow<strong>in</strong>g a traditional loan scheme or through pre-harvest loans (see paragraph 7.2.1). Accord<strong>in</strong>gto wholesalers <strong>in</strong>terviewed (2 <strong>in</strong> Paksong and one <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>ngam), monthly <strong>in</strong>terest rates range from 3 up to5%. Most farmers make these loans between July and September, at the end <strong>of</strong> the ra<strong>in</strong>y season which isgenerally the rice-gap period and they reimburse with robusta harvest <strong>in</strong> March. Thanks to credit,wholesalers have a certa<strong>in</strong> security on c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong>. Loans are granted based on the trust between thewholesaler and the producer. This is why their good knowledge <strong>of</strong> farmers is a key aspect.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 48


The type <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee bought depends on wholesaler’s strategy: some buy exclusively processed c<strong>of</strong>fee(arabica parchment and robusta unsorted green c<strong>of</strong>fee) and make their marg<strong>in</strong> on the sell<strong>in</strong>g whereasothers buy all types <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee, carry out all the process <strong>in</strong> their warehouses and get their marg<strong>in</strong> also onc<strong>of</strong>fee process<strong>in</strong>g. Wholesalers <strong>in</strong>terviewed purchased between 200 and 500 MT <strong>of</strong> robusta and 100 to 200MT <strong>of</strong> arabica dur<strong>in</strong>g 2006/2007 campaign. The average pr<strong>of</strong>it marg<strong>in</strong> ranges from 100 up to 500 LAK/Kg(for processed c<strong>of</strong>fee).C<strong>of</strong>fee is ma<strong>in</strong>ly sold to exporters who generally come to pick up the product <strong>in</strong> wholesaler’s warehouse.No contract is set between wholesalers and exporters. In most cases, they make a simple verbal agreementon the quantity and the price <strong>of</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee several days before the sell<strong>in</strong>g. In the past, most wholesalersused to borrow money from exporters for c<strong>of</strong>fee buy<strong>in</strong>g. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to wholesalers <strong>in</strong>terviewed, most <strong>of</strong>them stopped do<strong>in</strong>g it because the <strong>in</strong>terest rates were too high. It seems that now they manage to obta<strong>in</strong>loans <strong>in</strong> banks’ local branches <strong>in</strong> Paksong with <strong>in</strong>terest rates <strong>of</strong> 15%/year. Otherwise, they have thepossibility to get cash advances from exporters, with no <strong>in</strong>terests, if it’s done few days before the sell<strong>in</strong>g.Some wholesalers (especially <strong>in</strong> Paksong) have managed to create a large network <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee suppliers andcommercialize quite big amounts <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee to the po<strong>in</strong>t that they are start<strong>in</strong>g to th<strong>in</strong>k about the possibility<strong>of</strong> becom<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee exporters.5.2.3. Exporters5.2.3.1. Exporters’ characterizationIn <strong>Lao</strong>s, c<strong>of</strong>fee export is largely dom<strong>in</strong>ated by one big company (Dao Heuang) that commercializesaround 70% <strong>of</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee production (see Table 21). The rest is exported by less than five smaller importexportcompanies closely l<strong>in</strong>ked to a small number <strong>of</strong> importer local agents. The general scheme <strong>of</strong>export<strong>in</strong>g sector has been simplified <strong>in</strong> comparison to 1999 as some categories <strong>of</strong> actors like local c<strong>of</strong>feetraders and brokers are not operat<strong>in</strong>g anymore (<strong>PDR</strong>PB, 1999).Under the name “exporters” we can actually f<strong>in</strong>d different types <strong>of</strong> agents. Many c<strong>of</strong>fee exporters areimport-export societies from Pakse specialized <strong>in</strong> the import <strong>of</strong> manufactured goods and the export <strong>of</strong>agricultural products (c<strong>of</strong>fee, rice, soybeans, peanuts, etc.) as a way to obta<strong>in</strong> foreign currency. Somec<strong>of</strong>fee exporters are <strong>in</strong> the same time c<strong>of</strong>fee planters (on land concessions) and there are some exportersregistered <strong>in</strong> the exporters’ association but that never really deal physically with c<strong>of</strong>fee. They provide“export services” to other companies that don’t have an exporter license. F<strong>in</strong>ally, a bunch <strong>of</strong> farmergroups have started to export high quality c<strong>of</strong>fee to niche markets.The <strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee Association (exporters’ association)In <strong>Lao</strong>s, some c<strong>of</strong>fee export<strong>in</strong>g companies and local roasters have gathered <strong>in</strong> a private organizationunder the supervision <strong>of</strong> the Chamber <strong>of</strong> Commerce called the <strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee Association (LCA). This entitywas created through a Prime M<strong>in</strong>ister’s decree <strong>in</strong> 1994 with the view <strong>of</strong> strengthen<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee export sectorand centraliz<strong>in</strong>g all export related data. Its creation engendered a cartel situation as LCA members arethe only allowed export<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee. In exchange, they have to pay a contribution for the association’sfunction<strong>in</strong>g 23 . Any other non-member company (national or foreign) will<strong>in</strong>g to export c<strong>of</strong>fee from <strong>Lao</strong>s iscompelled to do it through one <strong>of</strong> these companies (they get a commission on the sale <strong>in</strong> exchange <strong>of</strong>carry<strong>in</strong>g out all export procedures).A new export<strong>in</strong>g company must fill several conditions <strong>in</strong> order to jo<strong>in</strong> the LCA: the most important oneis to have a certa<strong>in</strong> level <strong>of</strong> capital <strong>in</strong> order to get an exporter license from the trade department. Then, anapplication is submitted to the LCA direct<strong>in</strong>g board that will make a decision accord<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>ternalcriteria. Let’s note that none <strong>of</strong> the farmers’ export<strong>in</strong>g groups is member <strong>of</strong> this association.23 Companies have to pay to LCA a fixed annual contribution as well as 20 Kip/Kg <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee exported<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 49


Their ma<strong>in</strong> action on physical c<strong>of</strong>fee is to put it <strong>in</strong>to a merchantable form (FAQ green c<strong>of</strong>fee accord<strong>in</strong>g toimporters’ criteria). To that matter, they generally re-dry c<strong>of</strong>fee (as <strong>in</strong> many cases the humidity rate is stillvery high when the product arrives to the warehouse).Most exporters specialized <strong>in</strong> the sell<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee (robusta and arabica) without quality standards (FAQc<strong>of</strong>fee). In the past years, c<strong>of</strong>fee export circuit has been simplified as exporters have gotten closer to c<strong>of</strong>feeproduction. This goes from the build<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> warehouses and c<strong>of</strong>fee process<strong>in</strong>g units near production areasto the complete <strong>in</strong>tegration <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee production <strong>in</strong> the case <strong>of</strong> planter-exporters. However, they still havea quite limited role regard<strong>in</strong>g many downstream activities (sett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> commercial contracts, seek<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong>new markets or even price negotiations) as these aspects are generally undertaken by local importeragents.The strategy <strong>of</strong> most <strong>Lao</strong> exporters consists <strong>in</strong> seek<strong>in</strong>g a short term pr<strong>of</strong>it by sell<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee to the highestbidder. This has been possible thanks to an advantageous market frame, a susta<strong>in</strong>ed demand <strong>of</strong> this type<strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ternational market, a quite permissive quality control system and very lowtransformation costs. The ma<strong>in</strong> consequence has been the sett<strong>in</strong>g up <strong>of</strong> a system that doesn’t rewardc<strong>of</strong>fee quality at all stages <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee trade (from producer to exporter). Besides, such strategy impedes thesett<strong>in</strong>g up <strong>of</strong> long-term and trustful relations between buyers and exporters, which confirm the reputation<strong>of</strong> unreliability <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> agents <strong>in</strong> the eyes <strong>of</strong> some buyers.However, <strong>in</strong> the past few years new categories <strong>of</strong> actors with more complex strategies have started todevelop. Indeed, the recent development <strong>of</strong> arabica has brought a certa<strong>in</strong> diversification to <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeexport sector which has been stimulated by the arrival <strong>of</strong> new species, process<strong>in</strong>g techniques as well asnew potential markets. As a result, we can now differentiate a few categories <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exporters accord<strong>in</strong>gto different criteria such as market strategy, the type <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exported, the l<strong>in</strong>k to c<strong>of</strong>fee production, thedest<strong>in</strong>ation markets, etc. (See Table 21 <strong>in</strong> page 51).There is a great concentration <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee export as one s<strong>in</strong>gle company is responsible for around70% <strong>of</strong> the exports. <strong>Lao</strong> exporters have specialized <strong>in</strong> the export <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee without qualitystandards (FAQ) accord<strong>in</strong>g to market opportunities. They have little hold over c<strong>of</strong>fee marketstrategy as their strategy merely consists <strong>in</strong> sell<strong>in</strong>g to the highest bidder. This role is ma<strong>in</strong>lyplayed by local importer agents.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 50


Table 21: Exportersʹ typologyType <strong>of</strong> exporterExporter-wholesalersPlanter-exporter-wholesalerroasterPlanter-exportersFarmers’ groups(Dao Heuang company)NumberAround 10(4 or 5 active companies)1 1 or 2 3% <strong>of</strong> total c<strong>of</strong>fee exports Around 30% Around 70% 24 Less than 1% Less than 1%Average exported300 – 1,000 MT (80% <strong>of</strong> robusta 5,000-12,000 MT (80-85% <strong>of</strong>amount / year 25and 20% <strong>of</strong> arabica)robusta, the rest is arabica)Around 500 MT (100% arabica) Less than 50 MT (100% arabica)Qualities <strong>of</strong> exportedc<strong>of</strong>feeUndersized anddefective beansCommercial strategyUpstream c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong>BuyerRelations with buyerF<strong>in</strong>al dest<strong>in</strong>ationmarketsFAQ natural robustaFAQ washed arabicaSold to local roastersMarg<strong>in</strong> on the export <strong>of</strong> FAQc<strong>of</strong>fee without quality standardsForeign currency formanufactured goods’ importCredit servicesProducers and middle-buyers(from debt reimbursement andclassical buy<strong>in</strong>g)Generally one ma<strong>in</strong> buyer(through local agent)Indirect contact. Preponderantrole <strong>of</strong> trader’s local agentFAQ natural robustaFAQ washed arabicaRoast<strong>in</strong>g for domestic andregional marketsDiversification and high addedvaluethrough c<strong>of</strong>fee roast<strong>in</strong>g and<strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fee productionMarg<strong>in</strong> on FAQ c<strong>of</strong>fee exportCredit services.Producers and middle-buyers(from debt reimbursement andclassical buy<strong>in</strong>g)Private arabica plantationsDifferent <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>feetradersDepends on the buyer (directcontact or through local agent)FAQ washed arabicaSold to local roastersReturn on <strong>in</strong>vestmentMarg<strong>in</strong> on washed c<strong>of</strong>feeprocess<strong>in</strong>g and exportArabica plantations(process <strong>of</strong> cherries <strong>in</strong> company’swet-mills)Generally one ma<strong>in</strong> buyer(long-term relations)Direct contactEU, Vietnam EU, ASEAN (ma<strong>in</strong>ly Vietnam) EU, SwitzerlandWashed arabica (qualitystandards set by the buyer)Sold to local roasterExport<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> high quality c<strong>of</strong>fee toniche marketsMembers’ plantations(collective pulp<strong>in</strong>g mach<strong>in</strong>es, therest is done <strong>in</strong>dividually)Specialized c<strong>of</strong>fee roaster (USA,France, Japan)Indirect contact. L<strong>in</strong>k throughimporters’ representatives andNGO staffNiche markets (fair-trade andgourmet) <strong>in</strong> USA, Japan andFrance24 Quantities were given by exporters’ staff but couldn’t be confirmed with the figures from the LCA.25 Quantities vary every year because <strong>of</strong> the biannual variability <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee production<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 51


5.2.3.2. Export procedures, taxes and costsC<strong>of</strong>fee export implies several procedures and costs. At producers and middlemen level, ma<strong>in</strong> costs arel<strong>in</strong>ked to local taxes related to c<strong>of</strong>fee transport and a part <strong>of</strong> the tax on pr<strong>of</strong>its. The rules regard<strong>in</strong>g thesetaxes are very unclear and change constantly. Once the c<strong>of</strong>fee gets to the exporter warehouse, exportersmust go through several procedural steps <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g different certifications and tax payment as detailed <strong>in</strong>Table 22.Table 22: C<strong>of</strong>fee export procedures and costs <strong>in</strong> 1999 and 2006ProceduresAuthority1999 (1) 2006/2007 2006/2007USD/ton (2) Kip/Kg USD/ton<strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee Association contribution LCA 1.25 20 2.1Disease control certificate (« Phyto ») PAFO 0.8 1 0.1Quality control certificate Technology & Environment <strong>of</strong>fice 0.8 1 0.1GSP certificate Prov<strong>in</strong>cial Office <strong>of</strong> commerce 0 1 0.1Tax on pr<strong>of</strong>its (3) F<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>of</strong>fice 20.8 300 31.6Custom certificate Customs <strong>of</strong>fice Free Free FreeMeasurements CPTC <strong>of</strong>fice Free Free FreeSUB-TOTAL (adm<strong>in</strong>istrative costs) 23.65 323 34Transport from Pakse to the Thai border 15 70 7.4Shipp<strong>in</strong>g Chong Mek - Bangkok (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g harbor fees) 40 665 70SUB-TOTAL (transport costs) 55 735 77.4TOTAL EXPORT COSTS 78.65 1,058 111.4(1) Source: <strong>PDR</strong>PB c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> study, 1999.(2) MT <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee(3) Mode <strong>of</strong> calculation until 2005/2006 campaign.In 2006, more than 90% <strong>of</strong> adm<strong>in</strong>istrative costs (out transport-related costs) concerned the tax on pr<strong>of</strong>itpaid to prov<strong>in</strong>cial authorities. Dur<strong>in</strong>g our survey, representatives from the f<strong>in</strong>ance department as well asexporters were questioned on this issue. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to their answers, before October 2007 exporters had topay 300 Kip/Kg <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee exported to the tax division <strong>of</strong> prov<strong>in</strong>cial f<strong>in</strong>ance department.On the 5 th October 2007, the f<strong>in</strong>ance department released a new guidel<strong>in</strong>e on this tax with a new mode <strong>of</strong>calculation.Tax on pr<strong>of</strong>it = (Total c<strong>of</strong>fee export value x 5% x 35%)That is to say 1.75% <strong>of</strong> total c<strong>of</strong>fee valueThis is a tax on the benefits <strong>of</strong> any agent receiv<strong>in</strong>g a payment for c<strong>of</strong>fee sell<strong>in</strong>g (trader, wholesaler,exporter, etc.). In practice, for the 2007/2008 campaign, exporters have started to pay this tax with the newmode <strong>of</strong> calculation to the f<strong>in</strong>ance department <strong>in</strong> Pakse. Control is made by show<strong>in</strong>g the export contract,the letter <strong>of</strong> credit and the export <strong>in</strong>voice. It is important to remark that this tax is collected by Champasakprov<strong>in</strong>ce authorities at exporters level whatever the orig<strong>in</strong> <strong>of</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee is (even c<strong>of</strong>fee produced <strong>in</strong> otherprov<strong>in</strong>ces like Saravan or Sekong).Officially, c<strong>of</strong>fee traders and wholesalers at district level have to pay the same tax follow<strong>in</strong>g the samemode <strong>of</strong> calculation. In practice and accord<strong>in</strong>g to wholesalers <strong>in</strong>terviews carried out <strong>in</strong> November 2007,c<strong>of</strong>fee traders cont<strong>in</strong>ue to pay follow<strong>in</strong>g the former system. Before October 2007, big-scale wholesalershav<strong>in</strong>g got a license form the district trade department had to pay a tax for c<strong>of</strong>fee “transport” or“movement”. The mode <strong>of</strong> calculation was different <strong>in</strong> the two ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee produc<strong>in</strong>g districts, Paksongand <strong>Lao</strong>ngam. In Paksong, they had to pay a tax <strong>of</strong> 20 Kip/Kg <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee to the district’s f<strong>in</strong>ancedepartment. The tax was collected by district <strong>of</strong>ficials <strong>in</strong> wholesalers’ warehouses after hav<strong>in</strong>g roughlyestimated the total amount <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee that the wholesaler will potentially commercialize on that year. Thesystem was different <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>ngam where the tax was collected dur<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee transport <strong>in</strong> a check-po<strong>in</strong>toutside town (accord<strong>in</strong>g to truck’s load). In <strong>Lao</strong>ngam the amount was higher as wholesalers (ortransporters) had to pay 200 Kip/Kg <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee. It isn’t clear what happened with c<strong>of</strong>fee broughtdirectly to exporters’ warehouses <strong>in</strong> Pakse (did buyers pay the district tax?).<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 52


Accord<strong>in</strong>g to October 2007 decree, <strong>in</strong>dividual family producers and cooperatives are tax-exempt. It seemsthat it was already the case before, however, a farmers’ group export<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee has been pay<strong>in</strong>g a 150Kip/Kg tax to district authorities <strong>in</strong> the past years.As regards transport related costs, we observe the impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s be<strong>in</strong>g landlocked country as the cost <strong>of</strong>Thai shipp<strong>in</strong>g companies represents 63% <strong>of</strong> total export costs.In spite <strong>of</strong> a recent effort <strong>of</strong> clarification from the M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> F<strong>in</strong>ances, c<strong>of</strong>fee tax system rema<strong>in</strong>sopaque and is differently <strong>in</strong>terpreted by local authorities and ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee actors.5.2.3.3. Export quality standardsToday, only one exporter (Dao Heuang Company) has the necessary equipment for a good preparation <strong>of</strong>export lots. This is the consequence <strong>of</strong> the absence <strong>of</strong> quality standards and the lack <strong>of</strong> a recognized body(laboratory) that certifies these standards. The quality control certificate delivered by national authoritiesdoesn’t have any <strong>in</strong>ternational validity. As a consequence, most exporters haven’t set up the means toprocess c<strong>of</strong>fee accord<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>ternational quality standards. In most cases they merely proceed to a roughgrad<strong>in</strong>g and a manual sort<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee beans.Most exporters’ warehouses have dry<strong>in</strong>g cemented areas <strong>in</strong> order to re-dry c<strong>of</strong>fee beans if necessary. DaoHeuang has also vertical c<strong>of</strong>fee driers and some export<strong>in</strong>g companies have artificial driers. Then, c<strong>of</strong>fee iscleaned and sorted. Only one exporter has the adequate <strong>in</strong>frastructure for export lots prepar<strong>in</strong>g (size anddensity sort<strong>in</strong>g mach<strong>in</strong>es for both species, colorimetric sort<strong>in</strong>g for arabica). Most exporters just carry out amanual sort<strong>in</strong>g to reduce the percentage weight <strong>of</strong> defects.Picture 15: Density grad<strong>in</strong>g mach<strong>in</strong>e (DaoPicture 16: Stock<strong>in</strong>g area (Dao Heuang company)Heuang company)Table 23: Ma<strong>in</strong> steps <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee export lots preparationInternational standard systemReceptionPre clean<strong>in</strong>g (metal pieces, foreign matters, etc.)Stones remov<strong>in</strong>gHull<strong>in</strong>gPolish<strong>in</strong>gGrad<strong>in</strong>g by sizeGravity sort<strong>in</strong>gColorimetric sort<strong>in</strong>gManual selection <strong>of</strong> defectsWeigh<strong>in</strong>g and bagg<strong>in</strong>gSource: Sallée, 2007.Most <strong>Lao</strong> exporters’ systemReceptionDry<strong>in</strong>gHull<strong>in</strong>gManual selection <strong>of</strong> defectsWeigh<strong>in</strong>g and bagg<strong>in</strong>g<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 53


Most <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee is exported as FAQ (Fare Average Quality) green c<strong>of</strong>fee with less than 12% to 13%<strong>of</strong> humidity, depend<strong>in</strong>g on the specie. The percentage <strong>of</strong> defective beans and foreign matters tolerated bythe buyer varies accord<strong>in</strong>g to the type <strong>of</strong> contract. In average, the threshold for black beans, broken beansand foreign matters ranges from 0.5 to 1%.In <strong>Lao</strong>s no c<strong>of</strong>fee quality standards have been set up. Thecountry lacks a recognized control body (laboratory).5.2.4. Importers, <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee traders and their local agentsA significant part <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee is purchased by a bunch <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee traders who have localagents <strong>in</strong> Pakse. In the past few years, the market for <strong>Lao</strong> export c<strong>of</strong>fee has been largely dom<strong>in</strong>ated by twoma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee traders whose agents <strong>in</strong> Pakse are very active: a company from Switzerland (Noble) andanother one from Poland (Product Promotion who sells most <strong>of</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee to another Polish companynamed Elite) 26 . It was very difficult to get <strong>in</strong>formation about these agents and their activities (lack <strong>of</strong> timeto make <strong>in</strong>terviews, need <strong>of</strong> a permission from their superiors to answer to our questions, etc.).Most local importer agents work follow<strong>in</strong>g the same scheme. International or regional representatives asktheir <strong>Lao</strong> agents to provide for a certa<strong>in</strong> quantity <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee and decide <strong>of</strong> the buy<strong>in</strong>g price. The share <strong>of</strong>each exporter largely depends on exporter’s purchas<strong>in</strong>g capacity as well as the relations with the localimporter agent. Generally speak<strong>in</strong>g these agents work <strong>in</strong> priority with big-scale exporters, Dao Heuang <strong>in</strong>the first place and 3 or 4 mid-scale exporters (those who are able to commercialize several hundred tonsper year).Besides their role <strong>of</strong> representations, these agents play different roles throughout export process. Atmarket<strong>in</strong>g level, they supervise the signature <strong>of</strong> contracts between the buyers and <strong>Lao</strong> exporters 27 , besidesthey are facilitators <strong>in</strong> price negotiations between <strong>Lao</strong> exporters and c<strong>of</strong>fee buyers as they are <strong>in</strong>permanent l<strong>in</strong>k with importers’ regional representatives (<strong>in</strong> Hanoi, Bangkok, etc.). They also play a role <strong>in</strong>the preparation <strong>of</strong> export<strong>in</strong>g lots as they are generally <strong>in</strong> charge <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee quality control. F<strong>in</strong>ally, theyensure the follow up <strong>of</strong> the product from Chong Mek check po<strong>in</strong>t until the shipp<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Bangkok.Most <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee is purchased by a bunch <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee traders through themediation <strong>of</strong> their local agents. Locally, they ensure the contact between buyers and <strong>Lao</strong>exporters and also play a role <strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee quality control and follow-up.5.3. Secondary actorsGovernmental actorsSeveral government and government-l<strong>in</strong>ked agents <strong>in</strong>tervene at different levels <strong>of</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>.Although there isn’t an <strong>in</strong>stitutional coord<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> actors (such as a c<strong>of</strong>fee board), differentgovernmental bodies are present at all levels <strong>of</strong> the <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>, though their role is <strong>of</strong>ten limited tooverall supervision, certificates delivery and tax collect<strong>in</strong>g as shown <strong>in</strong> Table 24.26 We don’t know what quantities are commercialized by each agent as it wasn’t possible to obta<strong>in</strong> export figures by purchas<strong>in</strong>gcompany from LCA.27 All export contracts are FOB Bangkok.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 54


Table 24: Role <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector secondary actorsC<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong><strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> levelProductionCommercializationExportLCASecondary actorDAFO/PAFODistrict authoritiesProjectsDistrict trade dept.Transport dept.F<strong>in</strong>ance dept.Prov<strong>in</strong>cial authoritiesTrade dept.F<strong>in</strong>ance departmentPAFOTechnology andenvironment div.Commerce dept.Custom dept.Chamber <strong>of</strong>commerceMICRole and actionNormally <strong>in</strong> charge <strong>of</strong> technical follow up and awareness. In realitydepends largely on project’s opportunities. No real action outside <strong>of</strong>projects.Collection <strong>of</strong> land taxesNumerous. Some are specific to c<strong>of</strong>fee sector (PAB, Jhai, Oxfam…)some are transversal (Small Holders, ADP, Sufford…)Delivers work<strong>in</strong>g licenses to wholesalersTransport taxAt district level, collection <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee “movement” taxAt prov<strong>in</strong>ce level, collection <strong>of</strong> the tax on benefit from exporters.General controlDelivers exporters’ licensesTax on benefit (on exporters). Mechanisms are very unclear as well asthe use <strong>of</strong> the taxDelivers the phytosanitary certificateDelivers a quality control certificateDelivers the GPS certificateControlSupervisionOfficially adm<strong>in</strong>istrative supervision. Role very unclearBanks and other credit service suppliersWe have seen <strong>in</strong> previous sections that for most upstream actors (producers, middle buyers) the only wayto access credit is through <strong>in</strong>formal credit services (pre-harvest loans, <strong>in</strong>formal loans, usury, etc.). At locallevel (Boloven Plateau), only big-scale wholesalers have access to formal credit (see paragraph 5.2.2).At export level, most big-scale exporters make cash loans at the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> the campaign (December-January) from big banks <strong>in</strong> Pakse (BCEL, LDB, etc.). The <strong>in</strong>terest rate depends on the risk credit grad<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong>the company which is calculated by the bank. In 2007, the <strong>in</strong>terest rates for c<strong>of</strong>fee export<strong>in</strong>g companiesranged from 12 up to 15% per year for loans <strong>in</strong> Kip (ma<strong>in</strong>ly used for c<strong>of</strong>fee buy<strong>in</strong>g). For loans <strong>in</strong> USD the<strong>in</strong>terest rates range from 6 to 8% per year (ma<strong>in</strong>ly used for <strong>in</strong>vestment, mach<strong>in</strong>ery, etc.). Accord<strong>in</strong>g to abank representative that works with more than 7 export<strong>in</strong>g companies, the m<strong>in</strong>imum amount borrowedby the companies is around 500 million Kip (around 50,000 USD). Companies will make several loansdur<strong>in</strong>g the c<strong>of</strong>fee campaign.Agricultural <strong>in</strong>puts’ suppliersBased on the <strong>in</strong>terviews <strong>of</strong> three agricultural <strong>in</strong>puts shop owners from Paksong, we can conclude thatvery few farmers use agricultural <strong>in</strong>puts <strong>in</strong> their plantations. The few farmers that can afford to buy thesek<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> products use ma<strong>in</strong>ly chemical fertilizers (46-0-0 or 15-15-15 formulas), herbicides and on a lesserscale pesticides that they generally buy at the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> the ra<strong>in</strong>y season (May-June). All theseproducts are imported from Thailand.Commercial plantations purchase their <strong>in</strong>puts directly from Thailand or Vietnam or from big shops <strong>in</strong>Pakse.The C<strong>of</strong>fee Research and Experimentation Center (CREC)The only research center work<strong>in</strong>g on c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s is the C<strong>of</strong>fee Research and Experimentation Center(CREC) located <strong>in</strong> Ban Itou (35 Km from Pakse). The CREC is a governmental <strong>in</strong>stitute under the<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 55


supervision <strong>of</strong> NAFRI (National Agriculture & Forestry Research Institute). Officially, its ma<strong>in</strong> missionsare:- Research about c<strong>of</strong>fee- Production <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee seedl<strong>in</strong>gs- Tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g- Promotion <strong>of</strong> good quality practices among producers- Promotion <strong>of</strong> other crops (fruit trees, vegetables) <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau.Until 2006, the CREC was supported by a FAO funded project with the view <strong>of</strong> upgrad<strong>in</strong>g localtechnologies <strong>in</strong> order to produce high quality arabica. Currently, there is only adm<strong>in</strong>istrative andtechnical staff (1 director and two technicians) and no research programs ongo<strong>in</strong>g. As regards tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gs,they are regularly held <strong>in</strong> CREC facilities but they are always organized and funded by external projects(PAB, Oxfam, etc.). As a consequence, CREC has focused on c<strong>of</strong>fee plants production (nurseries) that issold either to private companies, c<strong>of</strong>fee projects or directly to farmers.In the past 2 years, CREC has been sell<strong>in</strong>g around 900,000 c<strong>of</strong>fee plants per year. Last year, more than 80%<strong>of</strong> these plants were sold to two big private companies (Dao Heuang and Dak Lak). In the case <strong>of</strong> DaoHeuang, c<strong>of</strong>fee plants are given to farmers <strong>in</strong> order to develop arabica surfaces under the conditionfarmers will reimburse the plants with c<strong>of</strong>fee cherries once their plantations start to produce. The price <strong>of</strong>each c<strong>of</strong>fee tree varies from 100 up to 700 Kip depend<strong>in</strong>g on the quantity bought. Big companies obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g discounts when they purchase big quantities.This specific example illustrates the lack <strong>of</strong> support for c<strong>of</strong>fee research and extension <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s. Indeed,CREC function<strong>in</strong>g and strategy leans exclusively on external projects. Many <strong>of</strong> the activities and researchprograms launched dur<strong>in</strong>g former projects have simply stopped or are be<strong>in</strong>g abandoned 28 as there is noreplacement <strong>of</strong> temporary external fund<strong>in</strong>g. Moreover, the sensorial <strong>analysis</strong> lab is underutilized.Unlike many c<strong>of</strong>fee export<strong>in</strong>g countries, the implication <strong>of</strong> secondary actors(governmental, f<strong>in</strong>ancial, scientific, etc.) is either non-existent or very weak.Howeve, s<strong>in</strong>ce the past 15 years, M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture has a significantimpact through its projects (LUADP, <strong>PDR</strong>PB, PCADR-PAB, FAO, etc.).28 Variety test plots, cutt<strong>in</strong>g tests, variety tests launched under FAO program, etc.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 56


6. Ma<strong>in</strong> actors and activities <strong>of</strong> roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee domestic market6.1. <strong>Lao</strong> roastersRoasters’ characterizationIn <strong>Lao</strong>s, a very dynamic domestic market has developed <strong>in</strong> the last years. This market ma<strong>in</strong>ly usesdowngraded export c<strong>of</strong>fee (undersized and defective beans). As expla<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the section on domesticmarket (paragraph 4.2 <strong>in</strong> page 29), there is a strong segmentation <strong>of</strong> domestic c<strong>of</strong>fee market as regards thetype <strong>of</strong> products, the places <strong>of</strong> consumption, sell<strong>in</strong>g prices, the types <strong>of</strong> consumer, etc. This segmentationis reflected <strong>in</strong> roasters’ typology as different types <strong>of</strong> roaster have specialized <strong>in</strong> different market segmentsas shown <strong>in</strong> figures below.In the one hand, a bunch <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustrial or semi-<strong>in</strong>dustrial roasters have specialized <strong>in</strong> the production <strong>of</strong>European-style c<strong>of</strong>fee (with a very large dom<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>of</strong> 3 companies: Dao Heuang, S<strong>in</strong>ouk and <strong>Lao</strong>Mounta<strong>in</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee). On the other hand, local-style c<strong>of</strong>fee is produced by a bunch <strong>of</strong> small and mediumroast<strong>in</strong>g companies from Pakse and Vientiane, characterized by the use <strong>of</strong> hand-made roast<strong>in</strong>g mach<strong>in</strong>esand flavor additives. Among the 600 to 800 tons <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee used every year for domesticconsumption, 400 to 500 tons are transformed <strong>in</strong> local style c<strong>of</strong>fee whereas the other 200 to 300 tonsbecome pure-roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee.F<strong>in</strong>ally, there is an emergent market for <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fees with the sell<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>stant and 3 <strong>in</strong> 1 c<strong>of</strong>fees bysome local companies and the build<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> a freeze-dry plant by the biggest roast<strong>in</strong>g company (DaoHeuang).Figure 12: Scheme <strong>of</strong> local-style roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>Exporters and wholesalersDefective or small beansunsuitable for export13000-18000 Kip/KgSmall village buyersUnsorted green c<strong>of</strong>fee13000-18000 Kip/KgProducersUnsorted green c<strong>of</strong>fee13000-18000 Kip/KgGreen c<strong>of</strong>fee10-15 roasters produce local-style mixed c<strong>of</strong>fee (Pakse and Vientiane)400 to 500 tons/year100% Robusta blended with sugar (from 0% up to 75%), alcohol,margar<strong>in</strong>e, sesame…Poor quality packag<strong>in</strong>g (cellophane bags)Sell<strong>in</strong>g price: 12000 to 60000 Kip/Kg depend<strong>in</strong>g on the percentage <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeMiddlemen (transporters)Small market shopsRoastedground c<strong>of</strong>feeTouristsRestaurants, hotels,guest housesSmall market andstreet spotsLAO CONSUMERSBeverage<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 57


Figure 13: Scheme <strong>of</strong> “European-style” roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>Privatec<strong>of</strong>feeplantationsExporters/wholesalers(C<strong>of</strong>fee unsuitable for export)Cooperatives(Ex: JCFC,Oxfam)Producers•Dao Heuang•<strong>Lao</strong> Mounta<strong>in</strong>•Delta•ThevadaMorethan50%Vientiane m<strong>in</strong>i-marts8 Industrial and semi-<strong>in</strong>dustrial roasters (Vientiane and Pakse)Pure-roasted and <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fees•S<strong>in</strong>ouk•Paksong•Rosdee•VangGnaoDuty free,souvenirC<strong>of</strong>fee shopsTotal production200 to 300 tons/yearRestaurants,hotels…MarketshopsForeign residentsTourists<strong>Lao</strong>tians(midlle-upper urbanclasses)Figure 14: Simplified scheme <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fees <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>Internationalroasters branch <strong>in</strong>Thailand(Nestle, etc.)Local importerFreeze-dry plant(Indonesia, Germany,Spa<strong>in</strong>…)Greenc<strong>of</strong>feeInstantc<strong>of</strong>fee<strong>Lao</strong> roasters(Dao Heuang andS<strong>in</strong>ouk)ThailandCreamer,sugar,packag<strong>in</strong>g,etc.Vientiane m<strong>in</strong>imartsSmall city and marketshopsInstant and3 <strong>in</strong> 1c<strong>of</strong>feesMAINLY LAO CONSUMERSUpstream c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong>As expla<strong>in</strong>ed above, the domestic market <strong>of</strong> roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee ma<strong>in</strong>ly uses downgraded export c<strong>of</strong>fee.Downgraded robusta c<strong>of</strong>fee is used <strong>in</strong> both local-style and European-style c<strong>of</strong>fee preparation whereasarabica is exclusively used for European-style roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee mak<strong>in</strong>g. So far, we haven’t heard <strong>of</strong> acompany that roasts export quality c<strong>of</strong>fee. Although there has been some <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g experiences <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeroast<strong>in</strong>g by small farmers’ groups (Thevada, Vang Gnao), they rema<strong>in</strong> anecdotal and limited to very smallquantities.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 58


Roast<strong>in</strong>g companies generally purchase processed c<strong>of</strong>fee (green or parchment) either from exporters, <strong>in</strong>some cases (like some small roasters <strong>in</strong> Pakse) directly from producers and middle-buyers or they get itfrom their own plantations (Dao Heuang and Delta for <strong>in</strong>stance). Buy<strong>in</strong>g prices fluctuate accord<strong>in</strong>g to theperiod <strong>of</strong> the year. It was quite difficult to obta<strong>in</strong> reliable data on the price <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee from most roasters<strong>in</strong>terviewed.Table 25: Prices paid by roast<strong>in</strong>g companies <strong>in</strong> 2007Roast<strong>in</strong>g activityType <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feePrice (Kip/Kg)Downgraded export robusta (green c<strong>of</strong>fee) 9,000 – 13,000Downgraded export arabica (parchment) 10,000 – 14,000Downgraded fair-trade arabica parchment 21,000Source: Roasters’ <strong>in</strong>terviewsEuropean-style c<strong>of</strong>fee (pure roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee) is produced either <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustrial or handmade roast<strong>in</strong>gmach<strong>in</strong>es. Among the eleven roasters <strong>in</strong>terviewed, only two used <strong>in</strong>dustrial imported roasters (DaoHeuang and S<strong>in</strong>ouk). Other companies use either hand-made roasters or improved hand-made roasters.Hand-made roasters are very rustic mach<strong>in</strong>es made from oil barrels and us<strong>in</strong>g wood as heat source.Improved hand-made roasters use gas and have a simple temperature-control device.Picture 17: Hand-made roaster us<strong>in</strong>g woodPicture 18: Ma<strong>in</strong> local-style c<strong>of</strong>fee additive: meltedpalm sugarPicture 19: Improved hand-made roaster us<strong>in</strong>g gasPicture 20: Industrial imported roaster(Dao Heuang company)<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 59


All local-style c<strong>of</strong>fee is made <strong>in</strong> one <strong>of</strong> those handmade roast<strong>in</strong>g mach<strong>in</strong>es. Roasters add melted palmsugar (25 to 75% depend<strong>in</strong>g on the mix), margar<strong>in</strong>e, alcohol and other additives. These mach<strong>in</strong>es don’tallow controll<strong>in</strong>g the temperature <strong>of</strong> roast<strong>in</strong>g or cool<strong>in</strong>g which are key parameters <strong>in</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al quality <strong>of</strong>the product. Ma<strong>in</strong> technical characteristics <strong>of</strong> each type <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee are summed up <strong>in</strong> Table 26 and Table 27.Table 26: Roast<strong>in</strong>g technical characteristicsCriteria Local-style c<strong>of</strong>fee European-style c<strong>of</strong>feeC<strong>of</strong>fee usedMix/preparationType <strong>of</strong> roast<strong>in</strong>gmach<strong>in</strong>eRobusta (downgraded export quality, defectivebeans)C<strong>of</strong>fee and additives: Palm sugar (25 to 75%),alcohol, margar<strong>in</strong>e, sesame, etc.Proportions change from one roaster to anotherRustic hand-made (made from oil barrels)Robusta and arabica (downgraded exportquality, export quality?).100% c<strong>of</strong>fee. Pure robusta, pure arabica androbusta/arabica blendsImported Italian-style roaster or improvedhand-made roasterRoast<strong>in</strong>g capacity 20-40 Kg 10-20 KgHeat source Wood GasTemperaturecontrolNoneThermostatType <strong>of</strong> roast<strong>in</strong>g Generally dark roast<strong>in</strong>g. One hour <strong>in</strong> average. Medium to dark. 30 m<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> averageGr<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g Ground c<strong>of</strong>fee Ground and whole beansWith the development <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fee consumption, two local roast<strong>in</strong>g companies (Dao Heuang andS<strong>in</strong>ouk) have started to market their own <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fees (at the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fee was importedfrom Thailand). However, as there is still no freeze-dry<strong>in</strong>g plants <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s, these companies make their<strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> a different country (Indonesia, Germany, Spa<strong>in</strong>, etc.). C<strong>of</strong>fee is then mixed and packaged<strong>in</strong> roast<strong>in</strong>g companies’ plants. In the case <strong>of</strong> 3 <strong>in</strong> 1 c<strong>of</strong>fees, all <strong>in</strong>gredients (creamer, sugar but also thepackag<strong>in</strong>g) are imported (see Figure 14).C<strong>of</strong>fee products (downstream <strong>supply</strong>)In the past years, <strong>Lao</strong> roasters have managed to expand the domestic market by develop<strong>in</strong>g a wide range<strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee products (see Table 27) us<strong>in</strong>g aggressive and effective market<strong>in</strong>g strategies. Besides the sell<strong>in</strong>g totraditional retail<strong>in</strong>g places (m<strong>in</strong>i-marts, c<strong>of</strong>fee shops, restaurants, hotels, etc.), some roasters have set theirown consumption places like specialized c<strong>of</strong>fee-shops, c<strong>of</strong>fee stands, etc. where they can sell c<strong>of</strong>feebeverage and advertise their products.Table 27: Roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee productsʹ differentiation criteriaCriteria Local-style c<strong>of</strong>fee European-style c<strong>of</strong>feeBlends100% robusta, additives. Pure robusta, pure arabica and robusta/arabica(up to 75% <strong>of</strong> palm sugar) blendsRoast<strong>in</strong>g typeLight (“Scand<strong>in</strong>avian roast”, “city roast”)Unknown, but generally veryMedium (“French roast”...)strong (even burned)Dark (“Italian roast”, “Espresso roast”…)Presentation Ground Beans and groundPackag<strong>in</strong>gInformationSimple plastic or cellophanebagsNoneDepends on the brand-Cellophane bags-Multi-foil bags with degass<strong>in</strong>g valveQuite wide <strong>in</strong>formation for the consumer (weigh,blend, orig<strong>in</strong>, roast<strong>in</strong>g type, roast<strong>in</strong>g date, etc).Regard<strong>in</strong>g the quality <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee products, it is too early to launch a comprehensive market study as <strong>Lao</strong>costumers are relatively new c<strong>of</strong>fee consumers. However, we have the results from a cup tast<strong>in</strong>g tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>ghold <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau <strong>in</strong> 2007. Dur<strong>in</strong>g this tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g session, c<strong>of</strong>fee producers, roasters, exporters andother c<strong>of</strong>fee sector representatives were tra<strong>in</strong>ed to sensorial <strong>analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee through the sampl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong>some c<strong>of</strong>fee products commonly sold <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Lao</strong> market. Table 28 summarizes some <strong>of</strong> the results <strong>of</strong> thistast<strong>in</strong>g.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 60


Table 28: <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fees cup tast<strong>in</strong>g resultsType <strong>of</strong>c<strong>of</strong>feeDescription (2)1 Local-style Quite strong and low quality aroma. Strong body. Absence <strong>of</strong> acidity andaverage bitterness. Burnt flavors.N° (1)GlobaljudgmentAverage2 Local-style Very <strong>in</strong>tense and low quality aroma. Pronounced acidity and sourness. Very bad3 Local-style Intense aroma. Strong body. Low acidity and strong bitterness. Strong taste <strong>of</strong>burntWeak4 European Intense and good quality aroma. Good balance between body, acidity andbitterness. Strong ligneous aromas.Average5 European Strong aroma and bitterness. Strong chemical and burnt taste. Strongastr<strong>in</strong>gency.Very weak6 European Intense and average quality aroma. Earthy taste. Quite astr<strong>in</strong>gent Weak(1) For confidentiality reasons brands are not named(2) Cup tastes were carried out on a s<strong>in</strong>gle sample, on one timeAs we can see, the global appreciation <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fees is rather low. As a matter <strong>of</strong> fact, none <strong>of</strong> the samplestasted dur<strong>in</strong>g this tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g obta<strong>in</strong>ed a good global judgment.<strong>Lao</strong> roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee domestic market is very dynamic with very active actors, a wide range <strong>of</strong> products andstrong market<strong>in</strong>g strategies. It ma<strong>in</strong>ly uses downgraded export c<strong>of</strong>fee and roast<strong>in</strong>g techniques are not yetwell controlled <strong>in</strong> many cases. As a result, the global quality <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee rema<strong>in</strong>s quite lowaccord<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>ternational standards. So far, this hasn’t had a repercussion on domestic costumers asthey are quite new c<strong>of</strong>fee consumers. However, further efforts on global quality should be made <strong>in</strong> orderto meet the demands <strong>of</strong> an <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly exigent public.6.2. C<strong>of</strong>fee retail<strong>in</strong>g (domestic market)This issue was analyzed based on 42 surveys carried up <strong>in</strong> different retail<strong>in</strong>g places <strong>in</strong> Vientiane andPakse as well as <strong>in</strong>formation given by roast<strong>in</strong>g companies.The domestic market <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> is quite short as <strong>in</strong> most cases roast<strong>in</strong>g companies deliver theirproducts directly to f<strong>in</strong>al retailers (m<strong>in</strong>i-marts, c<strong>of</strong>fee shops, hotels, etc.). Ma<strong>in</strong> buyers <strong>of</strong> “European style”c<strong>of</strong>fee are foreign residents and wealthy <strong>Lao</strong> costumers liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> large cities (Vientiane, Luang Prabang,Pakse, etc.). They generally buy c<strong>of</strong>fee bags <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>i-marts and market shops or consume beverages <strong>in</strong>c<strong>of</strong>fee-shops, restaurants and hotels. On the contrary, ma<strong>in</strong> buyers <strong>of</strong> local-style c<strong>of</strong>fee are <strong>Lao</strong>tians <strong>in</strong>both urban and rural areas (but ma<strong>in</strong>ly urban).Accord<strong>in</strong>g to retailers’ survey results specific costumers’ request is their number one purchas<strong>in</strong>g criterionfor packaged roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee (35% <strong>of</strong> the answers). Indeed, it seems that many costumers ask for a specificproduct ma<strong>in</strong>ly based on publicity, special <strong>of</strong>fers or other costumers’ advice. Other major purchas<strong>in</strong>gcriteria are the brand and the sell<strong>in</strong>g price. Regard<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee beverage, the price is the first purchas<strong>in</strong>gcriterion (<strong>in</strong> 30% <strong>of</strong> the answers) followed by the physical characteristics <strong>of</strong> the beverage (the mousse <strong>in</strong>the case <strong>of</strong> espresso c<strong>of</strong>fee, the color, the aroma, etc.).Table 29: Example <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee products’ range <strong>in</strong> Vientiane m<strong>in</strong>i-marts for 3 major brandsNumber <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee product rangesNumber <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee products (types<strong>of</strong> packag<strong>in</strong>g and presentation)Dao Heuang9 (great diversity <strong>of</strong><strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fees)S<strong>in</strong>ouk<strong>Lao</strong> Mounta<strong>in</strong>C<strong>of</strong>fee7 840 21 46C<strong>of</strong>fee products are generally highlighted. In some m<strong>in</strong>i-marts <strong>of</strong> Vientiane there are entire shelf-spacesexclusively for c<strong>of</strong>fee products and <strong>in</strong> many places they are shown <strong>in</strong> strategic places <strong>of</strong> the shop (near theentrance or the checkout). Moreover, there is a wide choice <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee products accord<strong>in</strong>g to its orig<strong>in</strong>,<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 61


and, weight, specie, blend, roast<strong>in</strong>g degree, etc. (Table 29). In some m<strong>in</strong>i-marts there are more than 80different c<strong>of</strong>fee products.The sell<strong>in</strong>g prices depend on different aspects such as the type <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee, the mode <strong>of</strong> preparation, thebrand, the packag<strong>in</strong>g, the c<strong>of</strong>fee blend, etc. Table 30 summarizes the average prices for different categories<strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee products sold <strong>in</strong> different Vientiane retailer shops.Table 30: Ranges <strong>of</strong> sell<strong>in</strong>g prices for different categories <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee product <strong>in</strong> the domestic marketPureArabicaEuropean styleBlendRobustaLocal-stylec<strong>of</strong>feeImported<strong>in</strong>stantInstant c<strong>of</strong>fees<strong>Lao</strong> brand<strong>in</strong>stant<strong>Lao</strong> brand 3<strong>in</strong> 1 c<strong>of</strong>feeAverage price <strong>in</strong>LAK/Kg109,200 106,280 49,200 19,875 169,000 228,000 46,296In USD/Kg 11,5 11,2 5,2 2,1 17,8 24,0 4,9M<strong>in</strong> 92,000 88,000 40,000 13,000 150,000 180,000 40,741Max 122,000 152,000 76,000 30,000 220,000 360,000 70,370Source: Surveys from the <strong>Participative</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee Supply Cha<strong>in</strong> Analysis6.3. Domestic consumption <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeIt is very difficult to analyze the consumption <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> import<strong>in</strong>g countries as it is always used <strong>in</strong>c<strong>of</strong>fee blends or for <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fee mak<strong>in</strong>g. Therefore this chapter will focus only on national/domesticmarket.As described above, the domestic market is segmented accord<strong>in</strong>g to the type <strong>of</strong> product and consumptionhabits. A qualitative <strong>analysis</strong> focused on quotas approach has been achieved <strong>in</strong> 2007 with a survey on 170households <strong>in</strong> Vientiane and Paksé.As expected, the typology <strong>of</strong> consumers follows the 3 types <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee produced by roasters: consumers <strong>of</strong><strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fee, <strong>of</strong> European style and local/traditional style.Table 31: Domestic market: buyers and consumers typologyGroups <strong>of</strong> consumers Buy<strong>in</strong>g Consum<strong>in</strong>gInstant c<strong>of</strong>fee consumersBuyers <strong>of</strong> Dao c<strong>of</strong>fee more precisely “3 <strong>in</strong> 1”,want to have details concern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>gredients<strong>in</strong> that product.Buyers <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fee Nescafé, their criteria<strong>of</strong> buy<strong>in</strong>g is the packag<strong>in</strong>g.Young consumers <strong>of</strong> brands like Dao orNescafé, <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fee and “3 <strong>in</strong> 1”, theyadd sugar <strong>in</strong> their c<strong>of</strong>fees and consume lessthan once a day.European style c<strong>of</strong>feeconsumersBuyers <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>i-mart, worried aboutorig<strong>in</strong>.Buy<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee company, they wantc<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> beans.Consumers <strong>of</strong> S<strong>in</strong>ouk c<strong>of</strong>fee, liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>Vientiane, European way <strong>of</strong> consumption,hot black c<strong>of</strong>fee with sugar if too bad taste.Consumers <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> Mounta<strong>in</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee prefer tobuy c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> beans.Traditional/local stylec<strong>of</strong>fee consumersBuy<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> street spots or <strong>in</strong> market spot, nocriteria <strong>of</strong> buy<strong>in</strong>g, but want to know thebrand <strong>of</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee they are dr<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g.Habit-buy<strong>in</strong>g customers, no criteria <strong>of</strong> buy<strong>in</strong>gand no special wish concern<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>feepackag<strong>in</strong>g.Consumers <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee beverages. They dr<strong>in</strong>kdur<strong>in</strong>g the afternoon only occasionally.Consumers <strong>of</strong> ʺPaksong C<strong>of</strong>feeʺ or c<strong>of</strong>feewithout brand, liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Paksé, older,consume their c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> the morn<strong>in</strong>g, itʹs <strong>of</strong>teniced c<strong>of</strong>fee with sweetened condensed milk<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 62


In the produc<strong>in</strong>g prov<strong>in</strong>ce, the habit <strong>of</strong> consumption is very typical; they have hung on their habits for along time and they are not ready to change. C<strong>of</strong>fee is not really <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Lao</strong> culture outside the south <strong>of</strong><strong>Lao</strong>s.Roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee is ma<strong>in</strong>ly consumed <strong>in</strong> urban areas by locals, resident foreigners and tourists. Pure-roasted“European style” c<strong>of</strong>fee is ma<strong>in</strong>ly consumed by foreigners, whereas <strong>Lao</strong>tians ma<strong>in</strong>ly consume local-stylemixed c<strong>of</strong>fee.The k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> use is also different accord<strong>in</strong>g to the type <strong>of</strong> costumer. Foreigners and tourists ma<strong>in</strong>ly reflecttheir orig<strong>in</strong>al consum<strong>in</strong>g behavior; they prefer a sophisticated packag<strong>in</strong>g, an Arabica c<strong>of</strong>fee, and themoment <strong>of</strong> consumption is the most important for them, a convivial and pleasant moment with friends orfamily or a good way to do bus<strong>in</strong>ess at work. The fact that they feel a little bit nostalgic (homesick) whenthey speak about c<strong>of</strong>fee shows that they don’t f<strong>in</strong>d exactly what they want <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s. However, theiraverage consumption per capita is quite important. They purchase bags <strong>of</strong> ground c<strong>of</strong>fee and consumec<strong>of</strong>fee on a regular basis <strong>in</strong> specialized places such as c<strong>of</strong>fee shops or m<strong>in</strong>i-mart where the <strong>of</strong>fer (<strong>of</strong>European style c<strong>of</strong>fee) is the best. The “focus group” method revealed that the foreigners taste a lot <strong>of</strong>c<strong>of</strong>fee before mak<strong>in</strong>g their choice and when they f<strong>in</strong>d the best one for them, they keep it quite a long time,and then, they try another one…So, they are not totally satisfied with the c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>of</strong>fer <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s.On the other hand, most <strong>Lao</strong>tians ma<strong>in</strong>ly consume traditional style c<strong>of</strong>fee. They buy it ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong> market,where they choose either ground c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> a transparent cellophane packag<strong>in</strong>g, or directly <strong>in</strong> beveragewith sweetened condensed milk; most <strong>of</strong> the time they consume it iced.F<strong>in</strong>ally, there has been a very rapid development <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fees <strong>in</strong> the past years, especially amongstlocal consumers. At first, this market ma<strong>in</strong>ly used imported <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fee (generally imported fromThailand). Boosted by this success, some big roast<strong>in</strong>g companies <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s started to sell their own <strong>in</strong>stantc<strong>of</strong>fee (which is also imported; as well as sugar and creamer) to diversify their range <strong>of</strong> products. Thismarket <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fee concerns ma<strong>in</strong>ly young people but everywhere <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s (Vientiane and Paksé); it is<strong>of</strong>ten for an occasional consumption. In 3 <strong>in</strong> 1 c<strong>of</strong>fee, <strong>in</strong>gredients are generally sugar (54%), cream (37%)and c<strong>of</strong>fee (9%); the c<strong>of</strong>fee taste is not very important. These consumers do not have a c<strong>of</strong>fee culture, theydo not have models, and so, for them it is a good c<strong>of</strong>fee, which corresponds to their taste.Table 32: Characterization <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee consumption <strong>in</strong> domestic marketInstant c<strong>of</strong>fee consumers European style c<strong>of</strong>fee consumers Traditional style c<strong>of</strong>fee consumersWHO ?<strong>Lao</strong>tians and foreigners atworkForeigners and <strong>Lao</strong>tians with ahigher standard <strong>of</strong> life<strong>Lao</strong>tiansWHAT ? Pure <strong>in</strong>stant or “3 <strong>in</strong> 1” Arabica or blend They donʹt know (Robusta)WHEN ?C<strong>of</strong>fee break for foreigners /Afternoon for <strong>Lao</strong>tians.Morn<strong>in</strong>g and after lunch (more thanonce a day).Essentially <strong>in</strong> the morn<strong>in</strong>g but just oncea day.HOW ?With sugar and milk (ready toconsume with “3 <strong>in</strong> 1”).Black and hot. Add sugar if thec<strong>of</strong>fee is too bad.With sweetened condensed milk, hot oriced.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 63


Places <strong>of</strong> purchas<strong>in</strong>g are numerous but most <strong>of</strong> the time specialized <strong>in</strong> each type <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee. Foreigners havea good choice <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>i-mart, so they can try several c<strong>of</strong>fees and, if they know exactly what they want, theygo to c<strong>of</strong>fee shop. <strong>Lao</strong> consumers buy their c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> the market, where there is the biggest <strong>of</strong>fercorrespond<strong>in</strong>g to their habits.The study shows also that <strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fee and “3 <strong>in</strong> 1” are sold everywhere: supermarket, m<strong>in</strong>i-mart, c<strong>of</strong>feeshop and market.Table 33: Domestic market: places <strong>of</strong> purchas<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>feeM<strong>in</strong>i-Mart C<strong>of</strong>fee Shop MarketStreet spots(only beverage)Instant c<strong>of</strong>feeconsumersEuropean stylec<strong>of</strong>fee consumersTraditional stylec<strong>of</strong>fee consumers39% 5% 56% 0%41% 32% 27% 0%6% 0% 76% 18%(Based on 117 c<strong>of</strong>fee consumers <strong>in</strong>terviews, <strong>in</strong> Paksé and Vientiane)All these results show the complexity <strong>of</strong> segmented market for buy<strong>in</strong>g and consumption. To improveconsumption, it would be necessary: i) to “educate” the younger generations with c<strong>of</strong>fee consumption,type/“species” <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee, taste <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fees and ii) to promote the image <strong>of</strong> the Boloven Plateau and thetraditional know how. People <strong>of</strong> Vientiane and tourists do not know the Plateau or have a pejorativeimage <strong>of</strong> it. The objective will be to create or develop a better image <strong>of</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>in</strong> general whichwould enable every <strong>Lao</strong>tian to be proud <strong>of</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee produced <strong>in</strong> his/her own country.Like <strong>in</strong> many cases, a c<strong>of</strong>fee-produc<strong>in</strong>g country is not really a c<strong>of</strong>fee-consum<strong>in</strong>g country, first because it isnot cultural yet and then because “European style c<strong>of</strong>fee” is expensive for local consumers (same price asEurope with a very dist<strong>in</strong>ct standard <strong>of</strong> liv<strong>in</strong>g). The conviviality around a c<strong>of</strong>fee gathers only consumers.There is very little communication between producers and consumers about conditions <strong>of</strong> production, <strong>of</strong>post-harvest process and quality criteria. The example <strong>of</strong> w<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry communication could be a model.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 64


7. Organization <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee market circuitsA market circuit is def<strong>in</strong>ed by its size (volumes, market shares, etc.), the type <strong>of</strong> product exchanged, themarket<strong>in</strong>g strategy and the f<strong>in</strong>al dest<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> the product. Market<strong>in</strong>g circuits’ <strong>analysis</strong> is based on twodifferent aspects:- Agents’ strategies- Relations between agentsIn this section, we will first describe ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee circuits by emphasiz<strong>in</strong>g major actors’ strategies.Then we will describe the relations between these actors before analyz<strong>in</strong>g how the f<strong>in</strong>al value is sharedbetween all categories <strong>of</strong> agents (price structures).7.1. C<strong>of</strong>fee circuits characterizationIn the case <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee, ma<strong>in</strong> market circuits are determ<strong>in</strong>ed by the type <strong>of</strong> product exported (whichdepends on the specie and the process<strong>in</strong>g method), the type <strong>of</strong> buyer and the f<strong>in</strong>al dest<strong>in</strong>ation. Eachcircuit is then characterized by a specific quality <strong>of</strong> product (natural robusta green c<strong>of</strong>fee, washed arabicagreen c<strong>of</strong>fee, roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee, etc.), a specific market (conventional export market, niche markets, domesticroasted-c<strong>of</strong>fee market, etc.) as well as different strategies and relations between actors.Consider<strong>in</strong>g that, we can differentiate 3 ma<strong>in</strong> circuits for <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee. In order <strong>of</strong> importance:- The ma<strong>in</strong>stream export circuit (that <strong>in</strong>cludes two types <strong>of</strong> product: FAQ natural robusta andmost washed arabica)- The circuit <strong>of</strong> washed arabica for niche markets (exclusively for arabica)- The circuit <strong>of</strong> roasted-c<strong>of</strong>fee for domestic marketRemarks:-Although there is a small percentage <strong>of</strong> dry-processed arabica produced, it generally follows the samecircuit as washed arabica or it is sold to the domestic market.-Even if it is technically possible, no robusta is processed through the wet-method. However, there hasbeen some experiences <strong>of</strong> washed robusta sell<strong>in</strong>g (small amounts sold to Taiwan) and some opportunities<strong>in</strong> the near future (2 conta<strong>in</strong>ers to New Zealand <strong>in</strong> 2008).Circuit characterization7.1.1. Ma<strong>in</strong>stream FAQ c<strong>of</strong>fee export circuitMore than 99% <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee is exported through ma<strong>in</strong>stream commercial circuits <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g 100% <strong>of</strong>robusta and most arabica (see figures below). In both circuits, the f<strong>in</strong>al product is green c<strong>of</strong>fee withoutstrict quality standards (FAQ) and for which there is a price penalty (accord<strong>in</strong>g to some exporters). In bothcases, a significant share <strong>of</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee sold by farmers is unprocessed so a large part <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee process<strong>in</strong>g ismade at middlemen and exporters’ level.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 65


Figure 15: Scheme <strong>of</strong> natural robusta circuit*80% <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> exportsIndividual farmers40% Dried cherries – 60% Green c<strong>of</strong>feeLegend: 50%Dried cherriesUnsorted greenc<strong>of</strong>feeGreen c<strong>of</strong>fee50%Middle buyers andwholesalersShell<strong>in</strong>gExporter-wholesalersShell<strong>in</strong>gClean<strong>in</strong>g - sort<strong>in</strong>g – grad<strong>in</strong>g – bagg<strong>in</strong>gFAQ naturalRobustaC<strong>of</strong>fee traders/roasters (EU, Vietnam…)Importers’local agentsQualitycontrolFigure 16: Scheme <strong>of</strong> washed arabica circuit*20% <strong>of</strong><strong>Lao</strong>exportsLegendCherriesParchmentc<strong>of</strong>feeGreenc<strong>of</strong>feePrivate <strong>in</strong>vestors’plantations20%Wet process<strong>in</strong>gIndividual farmers50% Cherries – 50% Parchment80%Middle buyersand wholesalersWet process<strong>in</strong>gExporter-wholesalersClean<strong>in</strong>g - sort<strong>in</strong>g – grad<strong>in</strong>g – bagg<strong>in</strong>gFAQ washedArabicaWet process<strong>in</strong>gImporters’local agentsQualitycontrolImporters/roasters (ma<strong>in</strong>ly European countries…)<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 66


The follow<strong>in</strong>g table analyses the ma<strong>in</strong> actors, activities and products <strong>of</strong> this circuit:Table 34: Functional <strong>analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>stream export circuitActivities Actors Activities Exchanged productsPrimary cherryproductionPost-harvestactivitiesProduction <strong>of</strong>merchantableexport c<strong>of</strong>feeExportImportRoast<strong>in</strong>gIndividual farmersCommercialplantationsA part <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividualfarmersMiddle buyers andwholesalersSome exportersExporters and somewholesalersExporters(role <strong>of</strong> importers’ localagents)Shipp<strong>in</strong>g companiesInternational tradersRoast<strong>in</strong>g companies <strong>in</strong>import<strong>in</strong>g countriesRoasters <strong>in</strong> import<strong>in</strong>gcountriesCropp<strong>in</strong>g, harvest<strong>in</strong>gIn some cases sell<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong>unprocessed c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> the farmDry<strong>in</strong>gRobusta dry-process and shell<strong>in</strong>gArabica wet-processSell<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the farm or transport tobuyers’ warehousesRe-dry<strong>in</strong>g (<strong>in</strong> most cases)Hull<strong>in</strong>g (parchment)Grad<strong>in</strong>g, sort<strong>in</strong>g, bagg<strong>in</strong>g.Rough quality controlTransport to the borderExport<strong>in</strong>g procedures and taxesTransport to Bangkok and shipp<strong>in</strong>gShipp<strong>in</strong>g, receiv<strong>in</strong>g, sell<strong>in</strong>g.Sometimes grad<strong>in</strong>g (<strong>in</strong> their localbranch)Blend<strong>in</strong>g, roast<strong>in</strong>gInstant c<strong>of</strong>fee mak<strong>in</strong>gRobusta and arabica cherriesRobusta dried cherriesRobusta unsorted green c<strong>of</strong>feeArabica parchmentFAQ natural RobustaFAQ washed Arabica60 Kg bags <strong>of</strong> FAQ naturalRobusta and FAQ washedArabicaGreen c<strong>of</strong>fee (sometimesgraded and sorted)C<strong>of</strong>fee blends (<strong>Lao</strong> orig<strong>in</strong>mixed with other orig<strong>in</strong>s)Ma<strong>in</strong>stream circuit’s functional <strong>analysis</strong> shows a low level <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>of</strong> producers <strong>in</strong> all stagesrelated to c<strong>of</strong>fee process<strong>in</strong>g (especially for arabica). Unlike many other export<strong>in</strong>g countries, <strong>Lao</strong> producerssell a great part <strong>of</strong> their c<strong>of</strong>fee at very early stages: dried-cherries <strong>of</strong> robusta and arabica cherries (refer toTable 37 <strong>in</strong> page 71). Accord<strong>in</strong>g to farmers’ survey, the ma<strong>in</strong> reason for sell<strong>in</strong>g unprocessed c<strong>of</strong>fee is thelack <strong>of</strong> means to set up c<strong>of</strong>fee post-harvest facilities.Another remarkable fact is the relative shortness <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>stream circuit <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>. Indeed, not onlythere are few categories <strong>of</strong> agents <strong>in</strong>volved (producers, village buyers, wholesalers and exporters) butalmost half <strong>of</strong> the farmers (<strong>in</strong> the case <strong>of</strong> robusta) sell c<strong>of</strong>fee directly to exporters (refer to Table 38 <strong>in</strong> page72).In the ma<strong>in</strong>stream circuit, c<strong>of</strong>fee prices are fixed accord<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>ternational prices made <strong>in</strong> importercountries’ markets. The price <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> arabica is made accord<strong>in</strong>g to the <strong>in</strong>ternational price <strong>of</strong> “other arabicamilds” decided <strong>in</strong> New York market. In the case <strong>of</strong> robusta, the <strong>in</strong>ternational standard is the LIFFE pricefixed <strong>in</strong> London. In both cases, accord<strong>in</strong>g to exporters, there is a price penalty <strong>of</strong> 0 to 5 cents/Pound (100USD/MT) from <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee buyers. The ma<strong>in</strong> reasons would be the global reputation <strong>of</strong> the product andthe reliability <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> agents.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 67


Actors’ strategiesTable 35 summarizes the strategies <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee actors participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong>stream circuit.Table 35: Ma<strong>in</strong>stream export circuit actors’ strategiesAgent Type <strong>of</strong> agent StrategyProducers Individual farmers Ma<strong>in</strong>ly livelihood. Relatively extensive cropp<strong>in</strong>g system (robusta) witha m<strong>in</strong>imum risk.Diversification (arabica) with a view <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>crease and creditdependencyreduction.Farmers’ groups Livelihood. Coexistence <strong>of</strong> a low-risk extensive cropp<strong>in</strong>g system with amore <strong>in</strong>tensive system <strong>of</strong> high-quality c<strong>of</strong>fee production for high-valueniche markets.Private <strong>in</strong>vestors Return on <strong>in</strong>vestmentMiddlemen Village buyers Usury credit and marg<strong>in</strong> on c<strong>of</strong>fee salesWholesalers Usury credit and marg<strong>in</strong> on c<strong>of</strong>fee sales. For the biggest, c<strong>of</strong>fee export(<strong>in</strong> the near future)Exporters WholesalerexportersMarg<strong>in</strong> on c<strong>of</strong>fee exports and foreign currency for the import <strong>of</strong>manufactured goods.Credit services (to middle-buyers and farmers)ImportersBig wholesalerexporter-roasterPlanter-exportersInternational c<strong>of</strong>feetradersComplex strategy:Diversification and high added-value through c<strong>of</strong>fee roast<strong>in</strong>g and<strong>in</strong>stant c<strong>of</strong>fees mak<strong>in</strong>g.Marg<strong>in</strong> on c<strong>of</strong>fee exports.Credit services.Return on <strong>in</strong>vestment (c<strong>of</strong>fee plantation)Process<strong>in</strong>g and export <strong>of</strong> washed arabica from own plantation to thesame c<strong>of</strong>fee traderPurchase <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee with <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g organoleptic characteristics, withoutquality standards at a low priceIndividual farmers ma<strong>in</strong>ly follow a livelihood strategy based on a cropp<strong>in</strong>g system (robusta) that requiresvery little <strong>in</strong>vestment and workforce. With the re<strong>in</strong>troduction <strong>of</strong> arabica and the development <strong>of</strong> the wetmethodthey have had access to a new circuit (washed arabica) with higher prices. However, thisdiversification implies the sett<strong>in</strong>g up <strong>of</strong> a more <strong>in</strong>tensive system requir<strong>in</strong>g a higher level <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts (capitaland workforce). Middle-men and most exporters have a double-strategy <strong>of</strong> marg<strong>in</strong> on c<strong>of</strong>fee sales andcredit services. Only one company has developed a high added-value strategy through the development<strong>of</strong> roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee market. Importers’ strategy consists <strong>in</strong> purchas<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g product at a low price.99% <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> exports are made with<strong>in</strong> a circuit without quality standards. There is a poor product’squality control system at all stages <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee commercialization. F<strong>in</strong>al product is average qualitygreen c<strong>of</strong>fee for which there is a great demand but bought at a low price (price penalty).7.1.2. High-quality c<strong>of</strong>fee niche markets circuitIn <strong>Lao</strong>s, only a very small quantity <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee (less than 100 MT <strong>of</strong> washed arabica per year) is marketedthrough this circuit which represents less than 0.5% <strong>of</strong> total c<strong>of</strong>fee exports. The ma<strong>in</strong> actors <strong>of</strong> this circuitare <strong>Lao</strong>tian producers’ groups (as <strong>in</strong> Katouat and Vang Gnao villages and JCFC), <strong>in</strong>ternationalorganizations (Oxfam Australia and Jhai) and foreign roast<strong>in</strong>g companies specialized <strong>in</strong> Fair Tradespecialty c<strong>of</strong>fees. The role <strong>of</strong> organizations is to set up the l<strong>in</strong>k between producers and buyers, to carry outexport procedures and to supervise c<strong>of</strong>fee process<strong>in</strong>g (<strong>in</strong> order to meet buyers’ quality requirements).Farmers deliver exclusively arabica parchment (ma<strong>in</strong>ly from the Typica variety but recently also from thedwarf variety). As expla<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> previous sections pulp<strong>in</strong>g is carried out <strong>in</strong> collective wet-mills (setthrough the support <strong>of</strong> NGOs), whereas the rest <strong>of</strong> the process is carried out <strong>in</strong>dividually. F<strong>in</strong>alpreparation <strong>of</strong> export lots is done at group’s level. The follow up <strong>of</strong> NGOs technical staff is a key factor asthey are <strong>in</strong> charge <strong>of</strong> check<strong>in</strong>g that farmers’ c<strong>of</strong>fee match buyers’ quality standards.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 68


The price paid to farmers is calculated accord<strong>in</strong>g to the fair-trade price for south-east Asia plus a fair-tradebonus. Then, the group deduces all costs related to c<strong>of</strong>fee process and condition<strong>in</strong>g, cooperative staffsalaries, logistics, material, etc. In 2006, producers received 19,000 to 21,000 Kip/Kg (1.95-2.16 USD/Kg)Figure 17: Scheme <strong>of</strong> niche markets circuit*Less than 1% <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> exportsFarmersCollectivepulp<strong>in</strong>gGroup /cooperativeLegendCherriesParchmentc<strong>of</strong>feeGreenc<strong>of</strong>feeClean<strong>in</strong>g - sort<strong>in</strong>g – grad<strong>in</strong>g – bagg<strong>in</strong>gWashedArabicaLCA memberexporterExport<strong>in</strong>gproceduresNiche markets (Fair-trade, Gourmet) <strong>in</strong> USA, Japan, France7.1.3. Domestic roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee market circuitThis circuit was fully described <strong>in</strong> paragraphs 4.2.page 29 and 6.page 57.7.2. Relations between ma<strong>in</strong> actors7.2.1. Relations between producers and c<strong>of</strong>fee buyersFarmers have two different ways <strong>of</strong> sell<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee: they can either sell it dur<strong>in</strong>g the harvest period or theycan sell it to a middle-buyer or exporter several months before the harvest <strong>in</strong> order to obta<strong>in</strong> pre-harvestloans. This system has a double advantage for c<strong>of</strong>fee buyers. Indeed, not only they obta<strong>in</strong> substantialbenefits from usury credit but they also ensure c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong>.7.2.1.1. C<strong>of</strong>fee sell<strong>in</strong>g through pre-harvest loansWhen farmers are <strong>in</strong> need <strong>of</strong> cash, they have the possibility to borrow money by us<strong>in</strong>g their future harvestas a guarantee; farmers say they sell “green c<strong>of</strong>fee” or “café khiaw” <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> (because cherries are still greenwhen the c<strong>of</strong>fee is sold). Farmers can get pre-harvest loans either from village buyers, wholesalers orexporters. In our study 29 , 45% <strong>of</strong> the farmers <strong>in</strong>terviewed borrowed money through this system last year(66% <strong>of</strong> these loans concerned robusta, 24% arabica and 10% arabica and robusta). Small-scale poorfarmers are most likely to make pre-harvest loans as shown <strong>in</strong> Table 17 and Table 36.Table 36: Percentage <strong>of</strong> households hav<strong>in</strong>g made pre-harvest loans accord<strong>in</strong>g to their social statusRich* Medium Poor0% 33% 44%* In <strong>Lao</strong>s the social status <strong>of</strong> a household is decided by local authorities based on several criteria such as the type <strong>of</strong> house, the land, livestock etc. Itis not very clear how this scale is calculated or how it evolves <strong>in</strong> the time.29 A specific survey on c<strong>of</strong>fee sell<strong>in</strong>g was carried out <strong>in</strong> half <strong>of</strong> the households <strong>of</strong> the total sample, that is to say 200 households <strong>in</strong> 20villages.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 69


There are two modalities <strong>of</strong> loan:- The classical loan system <strong>in</strong> which farmers borrow money with a monthly <strong>in</strong>terest rate andreimburse it thanks to c<strong>of</strong>fee sell<strong>in</strong>g. There is a tacit agreement on the fact that farmers will sellmost <strong>of</strong> their c<strong>of</strong>fee to the lender.- The second system is similar, except that farmers reimburse the debt <strong>in</strong> k<strong>in</strong>d (c<strong>of</strong>fee) at a pricedecided <strong>in</strong> advance. This price is always below the market price at the moment <strong>of</strong> the sell<strong>in</strong>g (<strong>in</strong>most cases it is half the market price). Generally farmers deliver unprocessed c<strong>of</strong>fee (cherries ordried cherries).If the borrower is unable to reimburse his debt, the lender will give a penalty. Normally he extends thedebt by <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>terest rate (generally he doubles it). However, <strong>in</strong> some cases it happens that thebuyer takes livestock or farmer’s assets (motorbike, etc.) as a guarantee.In both cases the scheme <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sell<strong>in</strong>g disadvantages c<strong>of</strong>fee quality as the priority for farmers is thec<strong>of</strong>fee volume. Moreover, they can no longer benefit from the competition between c<strong>of</strong>fee buyers.Ma<strong>in</strong> modalities <strong>of</strong> these loans are summed up <strong>in</strong> Figure 18. These results come from farmers’ survey.Figure 18: Summary <strong>of</strong> farmers’ cash loans modalities% <strong>of</strong> farmers hav<strong>in</strong>g made cash loans 31% (sample <strong>of</strong> 200 households)Credit lengthLoan amountNumber <strong>of</strong>answers403020100153713< 7 7 to 10 > 10MonthsNumber <strong>of</strong>answers40 3430201310690< 1 1 to 2 2 to 3 >3Amount (million Kip)Average: 8,4 months, Median: 9 monthsNumber <strong>of</strong>answers40302010017Interest rates/month3830%Interest rangeAverage: 19%, Median: 17%53Average: 1,7 million Kip, Median: 1 million KipNumber <strong>of</strong>answers5040302010010L<strong>in</strong>k with c<strong>of</strong>fee dependency% <strong>of</strong> households hav<strong>in</strong>g made loans39 4110% to 50% 50% to 90% More than 90%% <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> HH <strong>in</strong>comeIn average, farmers borrow money 7 to 10 months before the harvest. The average amount requested is 1.7million Kip, but more than half <strong>of</strong> the households borrowed less than 1 million. The average monthly<strong>in</strong>terest rate is around 20%. F<strong>in</strong>ally, we notice that households that rely on c<strong>of</strong>fee for a great part <strong>of</strong> their<strong>in</strong>come are more likely to make loans. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to farmers’ <strong>in</strong>terviews, beside the payment <strong>of</strong> externallabor these loans are ma<strong>in</strong>ly used to buy rice or to provide for exceptional expenses such as illness orreligious ceremonies. A small percentage <strong>of</strong> the families <strong>in</strong>terviewed (around 5%) have made pre-harvestloans every s<strong>in</strong>gle year dur<strong>in</strong>g the past 5 years.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 70


Figure 19 allows visualiz<strong>in</strong>g the impact <strong>of</strong> pre-harvest loans <strong>in</strong> households’ economy. This figure only<strong>in</strong>cludes cash loans (it is the reason why the percentage <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>debted households is smaller than <strong>in</strong> Figure18). In average, cash loans represented 7% <strong>of</strong> the total c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> 2006. For 17% <strong>of</strong> farmers theamount <strong>of</strong> loans represented less than 10% <strong>of</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong>come, for 12% between 10 and 50% and for 3farmers (1% <strong>of</strong> the sample) cash loans stood for more than half <strong>of</strong> the total c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong>come.Figure 19: Ratio between cash loans and total c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong>come (sample <strong>of</strong> 200 households)Ratio cash loans / c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong>comeNumber <strong>of</strong> answers150100500137340 Less than10%25310 to 50% More than50%If we consider that around 45% <strong>of</strong> farmers make pre-harvest loans and that the average amount borrowedis around 1 million kip, the global need for c<strong>of</strong>fee pre-f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g would be around 6,750 million Kip peryear (around 700,000 dollars). Know<strong>in</strong>g that the total c<strong>of</strong>fee value can be roughly estimated <strong>in</strong> 34 millionsdollars; it means that farmers’ pre-f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g needs stand for only 2% <strong>of</strong> global value.Almost half <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee producers have to make <strong>in</strong>formal pre-harvest loans everyyear with quite disadvantageous conditions (high <strong>in</strong>terest rates, low sell<strong>in</strong>gprice…). And yet, their global f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g needs only represent 2% <strong>of</strong> total c<strong>of</strong>feeproduction value.7.2.1.2. C<strong>of</strong>fee sell<strong>in</strong>g dur<strong>in</strong>g harvest<strong>in</strong>g periodTen years ago, most <strong>of</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee was sold at farm level, at an early stage <strong>of</strong> process<strong>in</strong>g to village-buyers orc<strong>of</strong>fee collectors. Now, many farmers are able to sell processed c<strong>of</strong>fee directly to wholesalers andexporters outside the village. One <strong>of</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> reasons is the wider access to transportation means such astok-toks. In our study’s sample, 31% <strong>of</strong> the farmers <strong>in</strong>terviewed had a tok-tok and around 6% had a pickupor a bigger truck. The type <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sold also depends on the total production, farmer’s process<strong>in</strong>gcapacity and household’s cash needs.Table 37: Type <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sold by farmers dur<strong>in</strong>g 2006/2007 campaignType <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feesoldArabica% <strong>of</strong> farmers % <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeharvestType <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee soldRobusta% <strong>of</strong>farmers% <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeharvestCherries 55% 34% Cherries 10% 2%Dried cherries 14% 8% Dried cherries 35% 19%Parchment 40% 49% Unsorted green61% 79%Green c<strong>of</strong>fee 12% 9% c<strong>of</strong>feeSource: Household survey 2007 (sample <strong>of</strong> 200 households)Note: Totals above 100% as many farmers sell different types <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeIn 2007, 20% <strong>of</strong> robusta c<strong>of</strong>fee was sold without process<strong>in</strong>g (cherries and dried-cherries). As a comparison,<strong>in</strong> 1999 this percentage was around 95% (<strong>PDR</strong>PB, 1999). There is a different situation regard<strong>in</strong>g arabica.Dur<strong>in</strong>g 2006-2007 campaign almost 55% <strong>of</strong> the farmers sold cherries (and <strong>in</strong> a lesser scale dried cherries).The ma<strong>in</strong> reason is the perishability <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee red cherries that require an immediate process<strong>in</strong>g. Robustadried-cherries on the contrary can be kept for several days and transported. Farmers cannot sell processedarabica unless they have access to a wet-mill<strong>in</strong>g facilities right after the harvest.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 71


Another consequence <strong>of</strong> the lack <strong>of</strong> access to wet-mills is that more than 50% <strong>of</strong> farmers sold arabica c<strong>of</strong>feeto small village buyers liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the area who carry out c<strong>of</strong>fee process<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> their own wet-mills. In thecase <strong>of</strong> robusta, more than 65% <strong>of</strong> the farmers sold unsorted green c<strong>of</strong>fee directly to wholesalers andexporters as shown <strong>in</strong> the table below.Table 38: First c<strong>of</strong>fee buyersArabicaRobustaType <strong>of</strong> buyer % <strong>of</strong> farmers Type <strong>of</strong> buyer % <strong>of</strong> farmersVillage buyer 25% Village buyer 14%Neighbor village buyer 33% Neighbor village buyer 23%District town buyer 18% District town buyer 18%Exporter/wholesaler 16% Exporter/wholesaler 48%Farmer group* 21% Other 2%Source: Household survey 2007 (sample <strong>of</strong> 200 households)Note: Totals above 100% as many farmers sell to more that one type <strong>of</strong> buyer* Bias <strong>in</strong> the sample as villages with farmers groups are over representedMost buyers check c<strong>of</strong>fee quality us<strong>in</strong>g rough-empiric methods (see Table 39) and give penaltiesaccord<strong>in</strong>g to subjective appreciations. Humidity testers are hardly ever used except for one big export<strong>in</strong>gcompany and farmers export<strong>in</strong>g high-quality c<strong>of</strong>fee to niche markets (as buyers’ quality standards arehigher). In that case farmers generally borrow a humidity tester from the C<strong>of</strong>fee Research andExperimentation Center (CREC) <strong>in</strong> Ban Itou.Table 39: Ma<strong>in</strong> quality criteria and controll<strong>in</strong>g methods dur<strong>in</strong>g first c<strong>of</strong>fee sell<strong>in</strong>gType <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeArabica cherriesArabica driedparchmentRobusta driedcherriesRobusta unsortedgreen c<strong>of</strong>feeDefective beans Humidity rate Foreign mattersQuality criteria Control method Control method Control methodNumber <strong>of</strong> unripe greencherriesColor, homogeneity, CBBattacksRapidobservationRapidobservation- - - Rapid observationBit<strong>in</strong>gRapid observation- - - - - - Shak<strong>in</strong>g 30 , bit<strong>in</strong>g Rapid observationNumber <strong>of</strong> black and brokenbeans, CBB attacksRapidobservation Bit<strong>in</strong>g Rapid observationIf c<strong>of</strong>fee doesn’t meet the quality standards set by the buyer, the penalty is generally a price or a weighreduction go<strong>in</strong>g from 5 up to 20%.The buy<strong>in</strong>g price is always decided by the buyer and farmers have generally little power <strong>of</strong> negotiation. Inmost cases, c<strong>of</strong>fee is sold by Kg excepted for robusta dried-cherries which are <strong>of</strong>ten sold by bags <strong>of</strong> 80 Kg.In 2006-2007 campaign the average prices paid to producers were the follow<strong>in</strong>g:Table 40: Prices paid to producers dur<strong>in</strong>g 2006/2007 campaignType <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeAverageprice(Kip/Kg)Averageprice <strong>in</strong>USD (1) /KgM<strong>in</strong> Max MedianRobusta dried-cherries 5,600 0.57 3,100 9,000 5,500Robusta green c<strong>of</strong>fee 11,600 1.19 8,000 16,000 11,500Arabica cherries 2,260 0.23 1,000 2,800 2,300Arabica parchment 15,900 1.63 10,000 19,000 17,000Source: Farmers’ survey (sample <strong>of</strong> 200 households)(1) 1 USD = 9735 LAK (exchange rate February 2007)30 Buyers can roughly check the humidity rate <strong>in</strong> dried-cherries by shak<strong>in</strong>g the beans and hear<strong>in</strong>g the sound it makes.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 72


As we can notice, there is a great variability <strong>of</strong> prices paid to producers. This is ma<strong>in</strong>ly due to thedifferences between the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g and the end <strong>of</strong> the harvest period. Besides, sell<strong>in</strong>g prices may varyaccord<strong>in</strong>g to the location, the type <strong>of</strong> buyer, the terms <strong>of</strong> the sell<strong>in</strong>g (pre-harvest loan, regular sell<strong>in</strong>g), etc.7.2.2. Relations between exporters and upstream suppliersExporters buy most <strong>of</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee from middlemen and producers. Planter-exporters get arabica cherriesfrom their private plantations. Most exporters set contracts or <strong>in</strong>formal agreements with local middlebuyers<strong>in</strong> order to ensure c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong>. There are different types <strong>of</strong> relations between exporters andmiddle buyers:- Middle-buyers can be completely <strong>in</strong>dependent- They can be partially <strong>in</strong>dependent but l<strong>in</strong>ked to an export<strong>in</strong>g company- They can be c<strong>of</strong>fee collectors paid by an export<strong>in</strong>g companyIndependent buyers are not l<strong>in</strong>ked by a commercial contract. They sell c<strong>of</strong>fee to the higher bidder. Somebuyers are <strong>of</strong>ficially <strong>in</strong>dependent but punctually set short-term contracts with an exporter for a specificamount <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee and a specific price. The middle buyer commits to deliver that amount and takes the risk<strong>of</strong> any big fluctuation on c<strong>of</strong>fee price. Generally there is no problem as these small-contracts arecompleted with<strong>in</strong> few days. In most cases, c<strong>of</strong>fee buy<strong>in</strong>g is partially f<strong>in</strong>anced by the exporter. However,most buyers refused to tell the terms <strong>of</strong> such cash advances.C<strong>of</strong>fee collectors are middle buyers work<strong>in</strong>g exclusively for an export<strong>in</strong>g company. It can be either atrader from a district town or a farmer liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the village. They use companies’ trucks and money to buyc<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> different villages and normally don’t work on commission. Only the biggest export<strong>in</strong>gcompanies work with this type <strong>of</strong> agents.Some exporters also provide credit services to village buyers, wholesalers and producers. Regard<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>formal credit to farmers, one big export<strong>in</strong>g company has set up a system <strong>of</strong> credit based on the lend<strong>in</strong>g<strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee trees. Through this system, farmers get trees from the arabica dwarf-variety that they reimbursewith their c<strong>of</strong>fee production once the plantations start to produce. It wasn’t possible to know the actualterms <strong>of</strong> this type <strong>of</strong> loan.Local importers’ agents7.2.3. Relations between exporters and downstream actorsAs expla<strong>in</strong>ed before, <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s local importers’ agents play a very important role. First <strong>of</strong> all they are thema<strong>in</strong> contact between the <strong>in</strong>ternational buyer and exporters. Moreover, they ensure the follow up <strong>of</strong>c<strong>of</strong>fee quality <strong>in</strong> exporters’ warehouses by check<strong>in</strong>g the m<strong>in</strong>imum quality standards.In the last years, two ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee traders (one from Switzerland and one from Poland) havepurchased more than half <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exports. They rely on very active local agents that are <strong>in</strong> charge <strong>of</strong>f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g the sellers, c<strong>of</strong>fee quality control and follow up <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee shipp<strong>in</strong>g.Other secondary actorsAs regards governmental and government-l<strong>in</strong>ked secondary actors, we have already po<strong>in</strong>ted out the factthat we f<strong>in</strong>d them at all stages <strong>of</strong> the <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> but their action rema<strong>in</strong>s very limited. There is an absence <strong>of</strong>State-control as no norms or quality standards have been set up. In other export<strong>in</strong>g countries, a state bodyis <strong>in</strong> charge <strong>of</strong> verify<strong>in</strong>g the conformity <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee lots with the established standards. To that matter, mostcountries have set up certified laboratories under the supervision <strong>of</strong> the national c<strong>of</strong>fee board or c<strong>of</strong>feecouncil.7.3. C<strong>of</strong>fee price structuresBased on <strong>in</strong>formation collected from ma<strong>in</strong> actors, we set up a theoretical price structure for each c<strong>of</strong>feemarket circuit presented <strong>in</strong> Annex 7, Annex 8 and Annex 9 (pages 84 to 86). These price structures<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 73


epresent an average theoretical situation that allows visualiz<strong>in</strong>g the distribution <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> costs andmarg<strong>in</strong>s with<strong>in</strong> each circuit. It has been done with 2006-07 harvest which was a good year for prices andyields. Average annual price structures could be dist<strong>in</strong>ct.First <strong>of</strong> all, we notice that the price penalty <strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong>stream circuit is slightly higher than 100 USD/MTaccord<strong>in</strong>g to the contract prices given by exporters. This situation is very unclear: nobody really knows ifthere is a standard penalty for <strong>Lao</strong> orig<strong>in</strong>, why there would be also a penalty for washed arabica or whatare the reasons that would expla<strong>in</strong> such penalty. The amount <strong>of</strong> the penalty also varies accord<strong>in</strong>g to thesources (some importers say they don’t give penalties at all, some sources give the figure <strong>of</strong> 170 USD/MTbut most actors say it is around 100 USD/MT). In the case <strong>of</strong> arabica, the difference between the<strong>in</strong>ternational price and <strong>Lao</strong> contract prices is even higher (120 to 190 USD/MT). It is possible that someactors’ marg<strong>in</strong> might be higher than announced.Regard<strong>in</strong>g the price structure <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>stream washed arabica (Annex 8 <strong>in</strong> page 85); we can visualize thedifference on value’s distribution depend<strong>in</strong>g on the type <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sold by producers. When producers sellcherries they receive 33% less than parchment sell<strong>in</strong>g.F<strong>in</strong>ally, if we compare the ma<strong>in</strong>stream circuit to the niche market circuit, we notice that export costs arehigher for farmers’ export groups (103 USD/MT versus 76 USD/MT <strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong>stream circuit). The ma<strong>in</strong>reason is the district “c<strong>of</strong>fee movement” tax that is higher for farmers’ groups 31 and the commission paidto the LCA export<strong>in</strong>g company (for export procedures).In Figure 20 we have represented the share <strong>of</strong> the total value obta<strong>in</strong> by each category <strong>of</strong> actor. For exportcircuit, the f<strong>in</strong>al value is the price received by importers 32 . For domestic market circuit, the f<strong>in</strong>al value isthe price <strong>of</strong> roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee sold to the retailer.Figure 20 : <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee circuits value <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong>100%F<strong>in</strong>al value distribution amongst ma<strong>in</strong> actors80%% <strong>of</strong> f<strong>in</strong>al value60%40%20%0%Producer Middle man Exporter Trader/RoasterRobusta FAQArabica CherriesArabica National MarketArabica ParchmentArabica Fair TradeAs we can observe, producers obta<strong>in</strong> a larger percentage <strong>of</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al value <strong>in</strong> the niche market circuit(73.2%) and <strong>in</strong> a lesser extent <strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong>stream FAQ robusta circuit (60%). In this graph we can alsovisualize the loss <strong>of</strong> added value for farmers sell<strong>in</strong>g arabica cherries as they only get 32% <strong>of</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al valueversus 52% for parchment sell<strong>in</strong>g. F<strong>in</strong>ally, producers only get 9% <strong>of</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al value <strong>in</strong> the case <strong>of</strong> roastedc<strong>of</strong>fee for domestic market. For producers, it is evident that the access to the 2 ma<strong>in</strong>s markets <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong>31 For <strong>in</strong>stance <strong>in</strong> Paksong, a farmer cooperative pays 150 LAK/Kg whereas wholesalers only pay 20 LAK/Kg. And yet, accord<strong>in</strong>g tothe last regulation released by the F<strong>in</strong>ance department, farmer cooperatives are tax exempt.32 We have made the assumption that importers sell <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee at the <strong>in</strong>ternational price.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 74


<strong>Lao</strong>s, exportation <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee and roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee domestic market, would provide them better c<strong>of</strong>feeend-value share. This objective would be reach only through collective organization.The graph also shows that middlemen obta<strong>in</strong> a very small share <strong>of</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al value except for those whotransform arabica cherries. In that case they get 24% <strong>of</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al value. In the export circuit, exporters get<strong>in</strong> average 32% <strong>of</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al value. F<strong>in</strong>ally, we see that <strong>in</strong> the roasted market circuit the largest share isobta<strong>in</strong>ed by the roaster as he gets almost 80% <strong>of</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al value.Farmers obta<strong>in</strong> the highest percentages <strong>of</strong> the product’s f<strong>in</strong>al value for niche marketc<strong>of</strong>fee and robusta FAQ c<strong>of</strong>fee. On the contrary, they only get 32% <strong>of</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al valuewhen they sell arabica cherries. In that case, the added value is retrieved by middlemenwho carry out the wet-process. In the case <strong>of</strong> roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee circuit, roasters obta<strong>in</strong>almost 80% <strong>of</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al product’s value.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 75


8. Conclusions on <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector <strong>analysis</strong>A <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> is a very complex issue <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g different categories <strong>of</strong> actors, activities,markets, products, etc. In order to compile the ma<strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs and results <strong>of</strong> this study by highlight<strong>in</strong>g thestrengths and limit<strong>in</strong>g factors <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector we decided to use the SWOT <strong>analysis</strong> methodology.(Strengths - Weaknesses - Opportunities - Threats).There are two ma<strong>in</strong> steps <strong>in</strong> a SWOT <strong>analysis</strong>:First, we must draw up the list <strong>of</strong> strengths, weaknesses, opportunities and threats for <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector(Table 41). In the specific case <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>, we decided to group these results accord<strong>in</strong>g to 4ma<strong>in</strong> themes:• Production• Markets• Supply <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> organization• Institutional frameThen, the cross<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> these results <strong>in</strong> a SWOT matrix allows visualiz<strong>in</strong>g the outputs <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> strategies,as shown <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g table:OpportunitiesThreatsStrengthsWeaknessesStrategies to develop <strong>in</strong> priority“Bottleneck” strategiesStrategies that lean on c<strong>of</strong>fee sector Strategies that need to overcome somestrengths <strong>in</strong> order to take advantage <strong>of</strong> weaknesses <strong>in</strong> order to be viableexternal opportunities.Cont<strong>in</strong>gency strategiesStrategies that allow to reduce c<strong>of</strong>fee sector vulnerability by lean<strong>in</strong>g on its strengths andby tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to account c<strong>of</strong>fee sector weaknessesAn example <strong>of</strong> what can be a SWOT Matrix output is presented <strong>in</strong> Table 42<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 76


Table 41: Summary <strong>of</strong> strengths, weaknesses, opportunities and threats <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sector (SWOT <strong>analysis</strong>)C<strong>of</strong>fee productionC<strong>of</strong>fee markets (<strong>in</strong>ternational anddomestic)Supply <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>’s structure andfunction<strong>in</strong>gC<strong>of</strong>fee sector’s environment and<strong>in</strong>stitutional frameStrengths• Farmers process c<strong>of</strong>fee by wet-method (forarabica)• “Natural” production (no chemical <strong>in</strong>puts)• Farmers have adopted the “arabica dwarfvariety” cropp<strong>in</strong>g system• There is a potential for arabica surfaces<strong>in</strong>crease• Typicity <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> robusta (grown <strong>in</strong> uniqueagro-ecological conditions)• FAQ <strong>Lao</strong> robusta has a good ratioquality/price <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ternational market• Good image <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s (‘exotic touch”)• <strong>Lao</strong> arabica has managed to enter highquality niche markets• Small producer at world scale (possibleorig<strong>in</strong> niche specialization)• Small producer at world scale (little<strong>in</strong>fluence and lack <strong>of</strong> recognition)• Organoleptic defects on both types <strong>of</strong>roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee (local style and “European”)• Low consumption per capita (domesticmarket)• The history <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> robusta is based on thesell<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> low-price, low-quality c<strong>of</strong>fee forwhich there is a very high demand• Price penalty for <strong>Lao</strong> FAQ robusta• Good image <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s (exoticism)• Niche markets for high quality robusta(washed, altitude, GI, etc.)• Further expansion <strong>of</strong> niche markets for<strong>Lao</strong> arabica (Fair-trade, organic, etc.)• Potential <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>crease for domestic market• Organic certification for farms, producers’organizations, production areas, etc.• Reduction <strong>of</strong> price penalty for <strong>Lao</strong> robusta• Risk <strong>of</strong> fluctuation <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>feeprices• Development <strong>of</strong> a high quality segment<strong>in</strong>side domestic market and good image <strong>of</strong>“European-style” roasted c<strong>of</strong>fee• New c<strong>of</strong>fee consumption places• Short <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>, geographicallyconcentrated• A bunch <strong>of</strong> very dynamic actors (Dao,S<strong>in</strong>ouk, LMC) have developed and<strong>in</strong>novated c<strong>of</strong>fee domestic market• Producers are not organized• Un<strong>of</strong>ficial costs (“transport taxes”,discrim<strong>in</strong>atory local taxes, etc.)• Lack <strong>of</strong> contact between <strong>Lao</strong> exporters andc<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong>ternational market• Preem<strong>in</strong>ence <strong>of</strong> one actor <strong>in</strong> the <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>• Lack <strong>of</strong> a structure gather<strong>in</strong>g ma<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>feeactors• Monopole <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee exports (exporters’organization functions as a cartel)• Room for producers’ organizationstrengthen<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>side c<strong>of</strong>fee sector• Future creation <strong>of</strong> the c<strong>of</strong>fee board CNCL• Possibility to set up quality standards aswell as a controll<strong>in</strong>g entity (Lab)• Authorities’ will<strong>in</strong>gness to exploit highquality circuits (MAF and Prov<strong>in</strong>ces)• Fund<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions have <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g high quality c<strong>of</strong>fee projects(AFD, Oxfam, JICA, New Zealand, etc.)• Succession <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational projectswork<strong>in</strong>g on c<strong>of</strong>fee development (LUADP,<strong>PDR</strong>PB, PAB)Weaknesses• Lack <strong>of</strong> quality control system at all stages<strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong>• Lack <strong>of</strong> process<strong>in</strong>g means (speciallyregard<strong>in</strong>g c<strong>of</strong>fee dry<strong>in</strong>g and arabica wetmill<strong>in</strong>g)• Absence <strong>of</strong> a management strategy for soilfertility• Lack <strong>of</strong> knowledge on c<strong>of</strong>fee trees prun<strong>in</strong>g• Low <strong>in</strong>tensive cropp<strong>in</strong>g system (robustaand Typica) due to cattle transit adaptation• Availability <strong>of</strong> land for c<strong>of</strong>fee expansion• Room for quality improvement throughc<strong>of</strong>fee process<strong>in</strong>g (density selection, etc.)• Lack <strong>of</strong> access to a fair and transparentcredit system for harvest costs f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g• Absence <strong>of</strong> research and knowledgespread<strong>in</strong>g among c<strong>of</strong>fee actors• <strong>Lao</strong>s doesn’t belong to any <strong>in</strong>ternationalc<strong>of</strong>fee-related organization (ICO, etc.)• <strong>Lao</strong>s is a landlocked country whichengenders slowness at different levels(f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g, transport through Thailand, etc.)Opportunities• Cost-reduction by explor<strong>in</strong>g othershipp<strong>in</strong>g ways (Cambodia, Vietnam)• Better use <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee taxes (clarification andtransparency)Threats• Risk <strong>of</strong> a lack <strong>of</strong> labor for arabicaharvest<strong>in</strong>g (rapid surface <strong>in</strong>crease,migrations to Thailand, competition <strong>of</strong>commercial plantations, etc.)• Risk <strong>of</strong> shortage <strong>of</strong> dry-season ra<strong>in</strong>s(because <strong>of</strong> deforestation)• Massive utilization <strong>of</strong> chemical <strong>in</strong>puts <strong>in</strong>commercial plantations• Risk <strong>of</strong> importers’ diversion towards otherproduc<strong>in</strong>g countries because <strong>of</strong> an irregular<strong>supply</strong> (absence <strong>of</strong> long-term relations, lack<strong>of</strong> trust)• Pressure on land due to rubber tree andc<strong>of</strong>fee commercial plantations’ expansion,bauxite m<strong>in</strong>e, etc.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 77


Table 42: Example <strong>of</strong> SWOT <strong>analysis</strong> output <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> strategies for c<strong>of</strong>fee sectorOTS• Launch a recognition campaign <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> robusta <strong>in</strong>order to elim<strong>in</strong>ate the price penalty for FAQ robusta• Explore cheaper shipp<strong>in</strong>g ways (Cambodia,Vietnam) <strong>in</strong> order to reduce export costs• Strategy for the access and promotion <strong>of</strong> highquality<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>in</strong> niche markets (washed arabica,washed robusta, organic, organic fair-trade,Geographical Indication, etc.)• Program <strong>of</strong> promotion <strong>of</strong> domestic c<strong>of</strong>feeconsumptionW• Carry<strong>in</strong>g on with wet-method centers build<strong>in</strong>g anddry-method improv<strong>in</strong>g techniques <strong>in</strong> produc<strong>in</strong>gvillages• Strengthen<strong>in</strong>g and extension <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee producers’organizations.• Support<strong>in</strong>g organizations to reach export/greenand national/roasted markets.• Launch a global reflection about putt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to placea harvest pre-f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g system (banks, micro credit,turnover funds, etc.).• Sett<strong>in</strong>g up <strong>of</strong> a tax system that meets all parties’<strong>in</strong>terests (prov<strong>in</strong>ces, districts, exporters,producers…). A part <strong>of</strong> these taxes should f<strong>in</strong>ance thec<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> structures.• Sett<strong>in</strong>g up <strong>of</strong> quality standards and a control body(laboratory) <strong>in</strong> order to project a pr<strong>of</strong>essional andclear image <strong>in</strong>ternationally• Creation <strong>of</strong> a c<strong>of</strong>fee board (CNCL) andparticipation to <strong>in</strong>ternational c<strong>of</strong>fee entities andevents• Improv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> technical support<strong>in</strong>g structures(research and vulgarization)• Reflection (at 3-prov<strong>in</strong>ces level) about environment protection policy (especially regard<strong>in</strong>g chemicalproducts’ management and forest and water conservation)• Sett<strong>in</strong>g up <strong>of</strong> a prospective and scientific report about the impact <strong>of</strong> land concessions <strong>in</strong> the Boloven Plateau• Launch a reflection about the harvest labor issue with practical suggestions (Examples: regional adaptation<strong>of</strong> school holidays, th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g about the temporary migrations between lowlands and highlands, etc.)<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 78


9. Bibliography / References9.1. BibliographyBab<strong>in</strong> P., 1998. Etude du système agraire des terres hautes du Plateau des Boloven. Master course report.INA-PG, Paris, France, 106 p.Bourgeois R., Herrera D., 1998. Filières et dialogue pour l’action. La méthode Cadiac, Cirad, Montpellier,France, 175 p.Daviron B., Ponte S., 2005. La Paradoja del Café. Mercados Globales, Comercio de Bienes Primarios y laEsquiva Promesa del Desarrollo. Federación Nacional de Cafeteros de Colombia, OrganizaciónInternacional del Café y Fondo Cultural Cafetero. Bogota, Colombia, 299 p.Duris D., Bonnal P., Pilecki A., 2002. Filière du café au <strong>Lao</strong>s et stratégies paysannes, Cirad, Montpellier,France.Fabre P., Bonnet P., Despréaux D., Freud C., Lassoudière A. et Raoult-Wack A.L., 1996. Le concept defilière : un outil pour la recherche. Editions du Cirad, Notes documents n°24, Montpellier, France, 28 p.Goud B., Roche G., Soukphilanouvong P., Victor-Pujebet B., 1996. Projet de Developpement Plateau desBoloven. Etude de Faisabilite, Cirad, Pakse, <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong>.Malassis L. et Ghersi G., 1996. Economie de la production et de la consommation. Méthodes et concepts.Editions Cujas, 2 ème édition, Paris, France, 393 p.Matsushima Y., 2004. C<strong>of</strong>fee Economy <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong>: A review <strong>of</strong> development with regards to Chang<strong>in</strong>gTrade Environment. Post-graduate course student report, Tokyo University, Japan.Marsh A., Op De Laak J., 2006. Special F<strong>in</strong>al Report – Some Key F<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs, Future Issues and Interventionsfor the <strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee Industry. FAO.M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Forestry, 2006. Agricultural Statistics Year Book. Vientiane, <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong>, 83 p.<strong>PDR</strong>PB, 1999. La filière café sur le plateau des Boloven. Pakse, <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong>.Sallee B. 2007. Etude de faisabilité sur le café des Boloven. Programme d’Appui à l’établissementd’Indications Géographiques (PEIG), Pakse, <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong>UNDP, 2006, National Human Development Report. International Trade and Human Development,Vientiane, <strong>Lao</strong> <strong>PDR</strong>, 2006.W<strong>in</strong>tgens J., 2004. C<strong>of</strong>fee: Grow<strong>in</strong>g, Process<strong>in</strong>g, Susta<strong>in</strong>able Production, Wiley-VCH, We<strong>in</strong>heim,Germany, 975 p.9.2. Websiteswww.ico.org; website <strong>of</strong> the International C<strong>of</strong>fee Associationwww.faostat.fao.org<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 79


AnnexesAnnex 1: Ma<strong>in</strong> characteristics <strong>of</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fea arabica and C<strong>of</strong>fea canephora speciesOrig<strong>in</strong>Grow<strong>in</strong>g agro-ecological environmentOther species grow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> thoseenvironmentsLatitudeC. canephora C. arabicaEquatorial forest West-Africa(From Gu<strong>in</strong>ea to Congo)Well distributed abundant ra<strong>in</strong>s.Hot temperatures, low altitudes.Banana, cocoaGenerally <strong>in</strong> equatorial low zonesOptimal ra<strong>in</strong>fall 2000-3000 mm 1500-2000 mmYield (kg green c<strong>of</strong>fees/ha)From 200 Kg (Ivory Coast,Cameroon) up to 1,500 Kg(Vietnam)Robustness Very robust tree Lack <strong>of</strong> vigorResistance to diseasesHemileia vastratix (leaf rust)Generally tolerant, sometimesresistantGenerally tolerantEast-Africa high Plateaus(Ethiopia, Kenya, Tanzania)Well distributed abundant ra<strong>in</strong>s.Cold periods (floral <strong>in</strong>duction).Fog and drizzle. High altitudes,Highland forests, Eucalyptus, P<strong>in</strong>etrees, vegetables, temperateclimate fruit treesGenerally <strong>in</strong> mounta<strong>in</strong>ous tropicalzones. Near the tropics, possibilityto grow arabica <strong>in</strong> lower altitudes(Cuba, Brazil, etc.)From 200 Kg (Venezuela) up to 3ton (Costa Rica, Colombia)Generally susceptibleNematodesSusceptibleDensity1,000-2,000 trees/ha1,000-10,000 trees/ha (for dwarfvarieties, it is 5,000 <strong>in</strong> average)ShadeGenerally no shadeAssociated with shade trees(generally legum<strong>in</strong>ous)Caffe<strong>in</strong>e content <strong>of</strong> beans 2 - 4.% (3% <strong>in</strong> average) 0.8 - 1.4% (1.2% <strong>in</strong> average)Annex 2: Ma<strong>in</strong> characteristics <strong>of</strong> arabica and robusta c<strong>of</strong>feesBrew characteristicsBeans’ process<strong>in</strong>grobustaStrong body, bitterness, may bearomaticMa<strong>in</strong>ly dry-process (some wetprocess <strong>in</strong> India, Indonesia,Uganda)arabicaLight body, acidity, aromaticMa<strong>in</strong>ly wet-process (with bigproduc<strong>in</strong>g countries do<strong>in</strong>g dryprocess like Brazil, Ethiopia andEcuador)Transformation yield (green/cherries) 22% 19%Quotation markets London, Le Havre New York, HamburgAverage <strong>in</strong>ternational price <strong>in</strong> 2006 67.5 cents/Lb 114.4 cents/LbMarket share <strong>in</strong> 2006 35-40% 60-65%Consumers’ image Bad image Good imageDest<strong>in</strong>ation marketsF<strong>in</strong>al productsSouthern Europe, NorthernAfrica, Middle-East.Pure robusta or c<strong>of</strong>fee blends(bottom-<strong>of</strong>-the-range products)Instant c<strong>of</strong>feesEspresso blendsNorthern Europe, USAPure arabica or arabica blendsSpecialty c<strong>of</strong>feesOrig<strong>in</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fees<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 80


Annex 3: C<strong>of</strong>fee process<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong> <strong>Lao</strong>s from beans to commercial green c<strong>of</strong>feeDry method (Robusta)Ripe cherries (“Mak Deng”)Sun dry<strong>in</strong>gDried cherries (“Mak Dam”)Shell<strong>in</strong>gUnsorted green c<strong>of</strong>fee (“Mak Som”)Sort<strong>in</strong>gGrad<strong>in</strong>gWet method (Arabica)Ripe cherries (“Mak Deng”)WithwaterPulp<strong>in</strong>gFermentationWash<strong>in</strong>gSun dry<strong>in</strong>gParchment c<strong>of</strong>fee (“Mak Khao Heng”)Hull<strong>in</strong>gUnsorted green c<strong>of</strong>feeSort<strong>in</strong>gGrad<strong>in</strong>gCommercial natural green c<strong>of</strong>feeCommercial washed green c<strong>of</strong>feeAnnex 4: International c<strong>of</strong>fee prices (1975 – 2007)US ce nts/Lb350300250Robusta groupOther Mild Arabicas20015010050019761977197819791980198119821983198419851986198719881989199019911992199319941995199619971998199920002001200220032004200520062007Source: International C<strong>of</strong>fee Association ICO<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 81


Annex 5: Farmers’ survey village listVillage name District AltitudeLak 35 Paksong 920Katouat Paksong 1200Phou Oy Paksong 1310Houeixanh Paksong 1185Maysaisomboune Paksong 1000Somsanoukmay Paksong 930Beng Paksong 1245Denesavang Paksong 920Houeivay Paksong 1055Lak 45 Paksong 1110Nongbone Paksong 915Phoumakko Paksong 1220Nonglouang Paksong 1180Phoud<strong>in</strong>edeng Paksong 1180Xetapoung Paksong 1190Onh Noi <strong>Lao</strong>ngam 600Houeixeng <strong>Lao</strong>ngam 850Nambeng <strong>Lao</strong>ngam 905Sixiengmay <strong>Lao</strong>ngam 680Vang Gnao <strong>Lao</strong>ngam 835<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 82


Annex 6: <strong>Lao</strong> export c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> schemeCircuit <strong>of</strong> washed arabicas (20% <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> exports)PrivateplantationsWet methodIndividual farmers50% C – 50% PExporter-wholesalersWet methodImporter localagents80%Middle buyersWet methodClean<strong>in</strong>g - sort<strong>in</strong>g – grad<strong>in</strong>g – bagg<strong>in</strong>gQualitycontrol20%FAQ washedArabicaCommercialplantationsGeneral c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> schemeIndividual farmersVillage buyersand wholesalersExportersFarmers’groupsCircuit <strong>of</strong> natural Robusta (80% <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> exports)50%Individual farmers40% DC – 60% GCFAQ naturalRobusta50%Middle buyersExporter-wholesalersClean<strong>in</strong>g - sort<strong>in</strong>g – grad<strong>in</strong>g – bagg<strong>in</strong>gShell<strong>in</strong>gShell<strong>in</strong>gImporterlocal agentsQualitycontrolImporters (ma<strong>in</strong>ly Europe)LegendC: CherriesP: ParchmentC<strong>of</strong>fee flowsCash flowsImporter agentsImportersImporters (EU, Vietnam…)LegendDC: Dried cherriesGC: Unsorted green c<strong>of</strong>feeCircuit <strong>of</strong> washed arabicas for niche markets(Less than 1% <strong>of</strong> <strong>Lao</strong> exports)FarmersCollectivepulp<strong>in</strong>gLCA ExporterExport<strong>in</strong>gproceduresLegendC: CherriesP: ParchmentGroup / cooperativeClean<strong>in</strong>g - sort<strong>in</strong>g – grad<strong>in</strong>g – bagg<strong>in</strong>gWashedArabicaNiche markets (Fair Trade, Gourmet)<strong>in</strong> USA, Japan, France<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 83


Annex 7: Price structure for natural robusta <strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong>stream export circuitInternational price ICO (1) (March 07) <strong>in</strong> USD/MT (0.79 cent/Lb) 1,742International price ICO (June 07) <strong>in</strong> USD/MT (0.92 cent/Lb) 2,028Contract price FOB Bangkok (2) m<strong>in</strong> 1,600Contract price FOB Bangkok max 1,900Average contract price FOB Bangkok (USD/MT) 1,750Total shipp<strong>in</strong>g costs Chong Mek - Bangkok (USD/MT) 60Theoretical price FOB Chong Mek (USD/MT) 1,690Exporter pr<strong>of</strong>it (3) (<strong>in</strong> USD/MT <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee) 280Total Export costs FOB Chong Mek (USD/MT) 76Total Export costs FOB Chong Mek (LAK/Kg) 743Includ<strong>in</strong>g<strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee Association Contribution 20Quality control certificate 1GSP certificate 1ʺPhytoʺ (disease control certificate) 1Transport (Chong Mek) 70Tax on pr<strong>of</strong>it (Champassak Prov<strong>in</strong>ce) 300F<strong>in</strong>ancial expenses 350Theoretical exporter warehouse exit price (USD/MT <strong>of</strong> merchantable green c<strong>of</strong>fee) 1,334Exporter warehouse exit price (LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> merchantable green c<strong>of</strong>fee) 12,983Total condition<strong>in</strong>g costs (USD/MT non-merchantable green c<strong>of</strong>fee) 90Total condition<strong>in</strong>g costs (LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> non-merchantable green c<strong>of</strong>fee) 880Condition<strong>in</strong>g related costs (<strong>in</strong> LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> non-merchantable green c<strong>of</strong>fee)Weight losses due to dry<strong>in</strong>g (around 3%) 360Weight losses due to grad<strong>in</strong>g (around 5%); sold to local roasters 50Manual sort<strong>in</strong>g 200Export quality bags 120Bagg<strong>in</strong>g / weigh<strong>in</strong>g / stock<strong>in</strong>g / load<strong>in</strong>g 150Exporter warehouse entrance price (USD/MT) 1,243Exporter warehouse entrance price (LAK/Kg) 12,103Middle-buyer pr<strong>of</strong>it (LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> non-merchantable green c<strong>of</strong>fee) 1,000Total collect<strong>in</strong>g costs(USD/MT <strong>of</strong> unsorted green c<strong>of</strong>fee) 7Total collect<strong>in</strong>g costs(LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> non-merchantable green c<strong>of</strong>fee) 65Collect<strong>in</strong>g related costs (<strong>in</strong> LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> non-merchantable green c<strong>of</strong>fee)Transport village - warehouse 40District ʺc<strong>of</strong>fee movementʺ tax 20Bags 5Theoretical price paid to producer / Kg <strong>of</strong> non-merchantable green c<strong>of</strong>fee (USD/MT) 1,141Theoretical price paid to producer / Kg <strong>of</strong> non-merchantable green c<strong>of</strong>fee (LAK/Kg) 11,103Rate USD/LAK 9,735Sell<strong>in</strong>g rate at: February 1, 2007Source: BCEL(1) Buy<strong>in</strong>g contracts for <strong>Lao</strong> robusta are generally set accord<strong>in</strong>g to the LIFFE price which can be different from the ICOprice (generally lower).(2) These are average contract prices given by exporters dur<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>terviews.(3) Theoretical estimation <strong>of</strong> exportersʹ pr<strong>of</strong>it for 2006-07 campaign with good prices and high production. Exporters<strong>in</strong>terviewed speak about 200 USD/MT. The exporters’ pr<strong>of</strong>it is estimated between 100 and 300 USD/MT depend<strong>in</strong>g on theyear.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 84


Annex 8: Price structure for washed arabica <strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong>stream export circuitType <strong>of</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee sold by producers: Cherries ParchmentInternational price ICO NYC (December 06) <strong>in</strong> USD/MT (1.28 cent/Lb) 2,822 2,822International price ICO NYC (February 07) <strong>in</strong> USD/MT (1.22 cent/Lb) 2,690 2,690Contract price FOB Bangkok (1) m<strong>in</strong> 2,500 2,500Contract price FOB Bangkok max 2,700 2,700Average price FOB Bangkok (USD/MT) 2,600 2,600Total shipp<strong>in</strong>g costs Chong Mek - Bangkok (USD/MT) 60 60Price FOB Chong Mek (USD/MT) 2,540 2,540Exporter pr<strong>of</strong>it (2) (<strong>in</strong> USD/MT <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee) 350 350Total Export costs FOB Chang Mek (USD/MT) 76 76In LAK/Kg 743 743Includ<strong>in</strong>g<strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee Association Contribution 20 20Quality control certificate 1 1GSP certificate 1 1ʺPhytoʺ (disease control certificate) 1 1Transport (Chang Mek) 70 70Tax on pr<strong>of</strong>its (Champassak Prov<strong>in</strong>ce) 300 300F<strong>in</strong>ancial expenses 350 350Theoretical exporter warehouse exit price (USD/MT <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee) 2,114 2,114Total condition<strong>in</strong>g costs (USD/MT <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee) 420 420In LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee 4,090 4,090Condition<strong>in</strong>g related costs (<strong>in</strong> LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee)Weight losses due to dry<strong>in</strong>g (around 3%) 510 510Weight losses due to hull<strong>in</strong>g (around 18%) 2,960 2,960Weight losses due to grad<strong>in</strong>g (around 5%); sold to local roasters 150 150Manual sort<strong>in</strong>g 200 200Export quality bags 120 120Process<strong>in</strong>g / bagg<strong>in</strong>g / weigh<strong>in</strong>g / stock<strong>in</strong>g / load<strong>in</strong>g 150 150Theoretical exporter warehouse entrance price (USD/MT <strong>of</strong> parchment) 1,694 1,694In LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> parchment) 16,487 16,487Middle-buyer pr<strong>of</strong>it (LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> parchment equivalent) 5,000 1,500Total collect<strong>in</strong>g costs(USD/MT <strong>of</strong> parchment equivalent) 156 7In LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> parchment equivalent 1,520 65Collect<strong>in</strong>g related costs (<strong>in</strong> LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> parchment equivalent)Transport village - warehouse 174 40District ʺc<strong>of</strong>fee movementʺ tax 20 20Wet process<strong>in</strong>g costs / Kg <strong>of</strong> parchment equivalent (labor, electricity, etc.) 1,304 0Bags 22 5Theoretical price paid to producer(USD/MT <strong>of</strong> parchment equivalent) 1,024 1,533Theoretical price paid to producer(LAK/ Kg <strong>of</strong> parchment equivalent) 9,967 14,922Theoretical yield dried parchment / cherry beans 23%Theoretical price paid to producers (LAK/ Kg <strong>of</strong> cherry beans) 2,292Rate USD/LAK 9,735Sell<strong>in</strong>g rate at: February 1, 2007Source: BCEL(1) These are average contract prices given by exporters dur<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>terviews.(2) These are theoretical estimations <strong>of</strong> exportersʹ and middle-buyers’ pr<strong>of</strong>its for 2006-07 campaign.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 85


Annex 9: Price structure for washed arabica <strong>in</strong> niche market circuit (example <strong>of</strong> farmers’ export groups)Fair-trade contract bottom l<strong>in</strong>e price (USD/MT) FOB Chong Mek <strong>in</strong> 2006 (1,21 c/Lb)2,668It doesnʹt <strong>in</strong>clude the Fair-trade bonus (5c/Lb)Total shipp<strong>in</strong>g costs Chong Mek - Bangkok (USD/MT) 60Theoretical price FOB Chong Mek (USD/MT) 2,608Total Export costs FOB Chong Mek (USD/MT) 103Total Export costs FOB Chong Mek (LAK/Kg) 1,006Export related costs (<strong>in</strong> LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee)<strong>Lao</strong> C<strong>of</strong>fee Association Contribution 20Quality control certificate 1GSP certificate 1ʺPhytoʺ (disease control certificate) 1Transport (Chong Mek) 70District ʺc<strong>of</strong>fee movementʺ tax 150Tax on pr<strong>of</strong>its 300LCA exporter fee 83F<strong>in</strong>ancial expenses 380Price exporter cooperativeʹs warehouse (USD/MT <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee) 2,504Price exporter cooperativeʹs warehouse (LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> green c<strong>of</strong>fee) 24,379Total condition<strong>in</strong>g costs (USD/MT <strong>of</strong> parchment) 445Total condition<strong>in</strong>g costs (LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> parchment) 4,335Condition<strong>in</strong>g related costs (<strong>in</strong> LAK/Kg <strong>of</strong> parchment)Transport village - warehouse 50Weight losses due to hull<strong>in</strong>g (around 18%) 3,700Losses due to size grad<strong>in</strong>g (around 20%); undersized beans sold to local roasters 325Peaberries 3% (sold to local roaster) -540Manual sort<strong>in</strong>g 450Bags 200Process<strong>in</strong>g / bagg<strong>in</strong>g / weigh<strong>in</strong>g / stock<strong>in</strong>g / load<strong>in</strong>g 150Theoretical price paid to producers (USD/ MT <strong>of</strong> parchment) 2,059Theoretical price paid to producers (LAK/ Kg <strong>of</strong> parchment) 20,044Real price paid to producers (LAK / Kg <strong>of</strong> parchment) 19,000Assumptions:15% <strong>of</strong> undergraded beans are sold to a local <strong>in</strong>dustrial roaster at a price <strong>of</strong> 21,000 LAK/Kg5% <strong>of</strong> undergraded beans are sold to a local small roaster at a price <strong>of</strong> 10,500 LAK/KgPeaberries are sold at a price <strong>of</strong> 38,000 LAK/KgRemarks:Rate USD/LAK 9,735Sell<strong>in</strong>g rate at: February 1, 2007Source: BCELThe difference between the theoretical and the real price paid to producers can be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the costs related t<strong>of</strong>armersʹ group function<strong>in</strong>g (staff salaries, facilities, etc.) and Fair Trade certification.<strong>Lao</strong> c<strong>of</strong>fee <strong>supply</strong> <strong>cha<strong>in</strong></strong> <strong>analysis</strong> – Groupe de Travail Café (GTC) 86

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!