12.07.2015 Views

an experimental investigation of the interactions ... - Vlerick Public

an experimental investigation of the interactions ... - Vlerick Public

an experimental investigation of the interactions ... - Vlerick Public

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Vlerick</strong> Leuven Gent Working Paper Series 2011/11AN EXPERIMENTAL INVESTIGATION OF THE INTERACTIONS AMONG COMBINATIONSOF FORMAL MECHANISMS AND SOCIAL NORMSBART DIERYNCKFILIP ROODHOOFTFilip.Roodho<strong>of</strong>t@vlerick.comD/2011/6482/11


AN EXPERIMENTAL INVESTIGATION OF THE INTERACTIONS AMONG COMBINATIONSOF FORMAL MECHANISMS AND SOCIAL NORMSBART DIERYNCKKU LeuvenFILIP ROODHOOFT<strong>Vlerick</strong> Leuven Gent M<strong>an</strong>agement SchoolThe authors are grateful for <strong>the</strong> helpful comments <strong>of</strong> Eddy Cardinaels, Margaret Christ, Henri Dekker, Stijn Masschelein,Kristy Towry, Alex<strong>an</strong>dra V<strong>an</strong> den Abbeele, S<strong>of</strong>ie V<strong>an</strong>denbogaerde, Wim V<strong>an</strong> der Stede, Luk Warlop, Sally Widener, MarcWouters, particip<strong>an</strong>ts at <strong>the</strong> EAA Doctoral Colloquium 2008, <strong>the</strong> ENROAC Summer School 2008, <strong>the</strong> New Directions Conferencein M<strong>an</strong>agement Accounting 2008, <strong>the</strong> EAA Annual Conference 2009, <strong>the</strong> AAA Annual Meeting 2009, <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> Conference onPerform<strong>an</strong>ce Measurement <strong>an</strong>d M<strong>an</strong>agement Control 2009.Bart Dierynck - Accounting, Fin<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d Insur<strong>an</strong>ce, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven. Naamsestraat 69, B-3000 Leuven,Belgium. E-mail: bart.dierynck@econ.kuleuven.be. Bart Dierynck gratefully acknowledges fin<strong>an</strong>cial support from <strong>the</strong> ResearchFoundation Fl<strong>an</strong>ders (FWO) <strong>an</strong>d from <strong>the</strong> Limperg Institute.Filip Roodho<strong>of</strong>t - Accounting, Fin<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d Insur<strong>an</strong>ce, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven <strong>an</strong>d Accounting & Fin<strong>an</strong>ce, <strong>Vlerick</strong> LeuvenGent M<strong>an</strong>agement School. Naamsestraat 69, B-3000 Leuven, Belgium. E-mail: filip.roodho<strong>of</strong>t@econ.kuleuven.beContact:Filip Roodho<strong>of</strong>t<strong>Vlerick</strong> Leuven Gent M<strong>an</strong>agement SchoolPhone: ++32 16 24 88 36Fax: ++32 16 24 88 00E-mail: Filip.Roodho<strong>of</strong>t@vlerick.com2


ABSTRACTEmployees <strong>of</strong>ten make decisions that involve a trade-<strong>of</strong>f between improving <strong>the</strong> perform<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>own business unit or department <strong>an</strong>d improving overall firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce. Previous research hasshown that such decisions are shaped by formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms such as incentive <strong>an</strong>d informationsystems as well as by <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm. This study explicitly recognizes thatemployees are subject to multiple formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms <strong>an</strong>d investigates a specific aspect <strong>of</strong> acombination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms, namely <strong>the</strong> extent to which each formal mech<strong>an</strong>ism motivatesemployees to act in <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest. Relying on <strong>the</strong>ory from social psychology, wehypo<strong>the</strong>size that (1) combinations in which not all formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms motivate employees to act in<strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest (i.e. misaligned combinations) lead to a lower degree <strong>of</strong> employee decisionsthat are in line with <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest th<strong>an</strong> when all formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms motivate employees toact in <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest (i.e. aligned combinations) <strong>an</strong>d (2) descriptive social norms will driveemployee decisions in case <strong>of</strong> misaligned combinations but not in case <strong>of</strong> aligned combinations. Theresults <strong>of</strong> our experiment are consistent with <strong>the</strong>se hypo<strong>the</strong>ses. Our results contribute to <strong>the</strong> stream<strong>of</strong> research that investigates <strong>interactions</strong> between formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms <strong>an</strong>d social norms by explicitlytaking into account that firms implement multiple formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms <strong>an</strong>d by investigating <strong>the</strong> role<strong>of</strong> a typical characteristic <strong>of</strong> a combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>ismsKeywords: formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms, social norms, alignment, firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce3


I. INTRODUCTIONWhile a lot <strong>of</strong> firms have eagerly embraced intra-firm cooperation as a key aspect <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>irstrategy, <strong>the</strong> challenge that <strong>the</strong>se firms face is to to refrain employees from taking decisions thatbenefit <strong>the</strong>ir own department or business unit but harm <strong>the</strong> firm as a whole (Galbraith 2007;Jorgensen <strong>an</strong>d Messner 2009; Roberts 2004). Consequently, m<strong>an</strong>agers must underst<strong>an</strong>d howemployees c<strong>an</strong> be instigated to act in <strong>the</strong> best interest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm. Over <strong>the</strong> past several decades,researchers in several domains have cast light over <strong>the</strong> way employees take <strong>the</strong>ir decisions. A mainfinding is that employee decisions are influenced by <strong>the</strong> economic structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm. Typically, <strong>the</strong>economic structure consists <strong>of</strong> various formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms such as incentive systems <strong>an</strong>d informationsystems (Milgrom <strong>an</strong>d Roberts 1992). A burgeoning literature, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r h<strong>an</strong>d, demonstrates thatdescriptive social norms, which describe how things are usually done in a firm, are also veryinfluential in shaping employee decisions (Cialdini et al. 1990; 2000; Cialdini 2007; Cialdini <strong>an</strong>d Trost2010). Consistent with <strong>the</strong> findings <strong>of</strong> this line <strong>of</strong> research, firms invest a lot <strong>of</strong> money in social eventsto develop descriptive social norms that propagate <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> intra-firm cooperation. Thougha lot <strong>of</strong> studies have focused on ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> economic structure or <strong>the</strong> social structure as adetermin<strong>an</strong>t <strong>of</strong> employee behavior, recent efforts have begun to explore <strong>the</strong> <strong>interactions</strong> between<strong>the</strong> economic <strong>an</strong>d social structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm (Bloomfield <strong>an</strong>d Tayler 2010; Coletti et al. 2005; Fisher<strong>an</strong>d Huddart 2008).This study complies with <strong>the</strong> idea that <strong>the</strong> economic <strong>an</strong>d social structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm areintertwined <strong>an</strong>d provides <strong>the</strong>ory <strong>an</strong>d <strong>experimental</strong> evidence to suggest that <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>tcharacteristic <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economic structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm - whe<strong>the</strong>r all formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms are designed toinduce employees to act in <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest or not - determines <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> descriptivesocial norms for guiding employee decisions. The notion <strong>of</strong> alignment <strong>of</strong> a combination <strong>of</strong> formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms with <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest is inextricably intertwined with <strong>the</strong> observation thatemployees are influenced by multiple formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms when making decisions (Merch<strong>an</strong>t <strong>an</strong>d V<strong>an</strong>der Stede 2007; Roberts 2004). In this perspective, a combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms is alignedwith <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest if all formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms motivate employees to act in <strong>the</strong> firm’s bestinterest. Such a combination provides employees with a coherent message about <strong>the</strong> expectedbehavior. A combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms is misaligned with <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest if not allformal mech<strong>an</strong>isms induce employees to act in <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest. 1Despite <strong>the</strong> inconsistencywith equilibrium assumptions, misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms are highly prevalent in1 For ease <strong>of</strong> notification, we will use ‘aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms’ when we refer to combinations <strong>of</strong>formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms in which all formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms are aligned with <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest. ‘Misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong>formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms’ refer to combinations in which not all formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms are aligned with <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest.Note that this definition implies that one formal mech<strong>an</strong>ism has to be aligned with <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest.4


practice. Some firms, for inst<strong>an</strong>ce, heavily focus on incentive systems to instigate employees to takedecisions that improve firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce but do not pay attention to o<strong>the</strong>r formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms. Such<strong>an</strong> approach leads to <strong>an</strong> economic structure that sends out incoherent messages about <strong>the</strong> expectedbehavior (Rom<strong>an</strong> 2009). Misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms are also observed whenfirms ch<strong>an</strong>ge <strong>the</strong>ir strategy or during firm restructurings (Jorgensen <strong>an</strong>d Messner 2009). Despite <strong>the</strong>high prevalence <strong>of</strong> misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms, our underst<strong>an</strong>ding <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>influence <strong>of</strong> such combinations on employee behavior is ra<strong>the</strong>r limited, a shortcoming that weaddress with this study.The main intuition behind our <strong>the</strong>ory is that a misaligned combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>ismsdisperses <strong>an</strong> incoherent message about <strong>the</strong> expected behavior which will lead to ambiguity about <strong>the</strong>expected behavior. Our first hypo<strong>the</strong>sis states that this ambiguity decreases <strong>the</strong> extent to whichemployees act in <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest. Relying on <strong>the</strong>ory <strong>an</strong>d findings from social psychology,which states that descriptive social norms especially drive behavior in ambiguous situations as <strong>the</strong>ybecome more salient in such situations, we fur<strong>the</strong>r hypo<strong>the</strong>size that descriptive social norms shapeemployee decisions when combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms are misaligned but not when <strong>the</strong>y arealigned (Cialdini et al. 1990; Cialdini <strong>an</strong>d Trost 1998; Goldstein <strong>an</strong>d Cialdini 2010; Kallgren et al. 2000).In summary, whereas prior research has provided inconclusive results about <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>economic <strong>an</strong>d social structure for employee decision-making, we argue that <strong>the</strong> social structure ismore import<strong>an</strong>t for shaping employee decision-making when not all parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economic structuremotivate employees to act in <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest.We conduct <strong>an</strong> experiment in which <strong>the</strong> particip<strong>an</strong>t’s decision ei<strong>the</strong>r improves departmentalperform<strong>an</strong>ce or firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce. We m<strong>an</strong>ipulate two formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms (i.e. <strong>the</strong> employees’incentive system <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> information that employees receive about <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir actions onfirm perform<strong>an</strong>ce) <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms. The incentive system <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> information thatparticip<strong>an</strong>ts receive are ei<strong>the</strong>r focused on optimizing <strong>the</strong> departmental perform<strong>an</strong>ce or firmperform<strong>an</strong>ce. As such, we obtain combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms that are ei<strong>the</strong>r misaligned (i.e.one formal mech<strong>an</strong>ism motivates employees to optimize firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce while <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rmotivates employees to optimize departmental perform<strong>an</strong>ce) or aligned with <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest(i.e. both formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms induce employees to act in <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest). The descriptivesocial norms are ei<strong>the</strong>r focused on <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> improving departmental (no intra-firmcooperation) or firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce (intra-firm cooperation).Our results are tw<strong>of</strong>old. First, we demonstrate that misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms lower <strong>the</strong> extent to which employee decisions are in line with <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest.This result is consistent with earlier research in psychology <strong>an</strong>d accounting (Gaertner et al. 2002;5


Rowe 2004). Import<strong>an</strong>tly, we also obtain this result if <strong>the</strong> misaligned combination <strong>of</strong> formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms is embedded in descriptive social norms that promote intra-firm cooperation. Thus,descriptive social norms that emphasize <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> intra-firm cooperation to improve firmperform<strong>an</strong>ce c<strong>an</strong> never correct for <strong>the</strong> ambiguity that is caused by misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms. More notably, we find evidence for our main hypo<strong>the</strong>sis that descriptive social normsare a more import<strong>an</strong>t driver <strong>of</strong> employee decisions when combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms aremisaligned. Specifically, descriptive social norms do not influence employee decisions in case <strong>of</strong>aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms while employee decisions in case <strong>of</strong> misalignedcombinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms are more in line with <strong>the</strong> firm’s interests if <strong>the</strong> descriptive socialnorms emphasize <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> intra-firm cooperation th<strong>an</strong> when <strong>the</strong>y do not emphasize intrafirmcooperation.The study’s primary contribution lies in <strong>the</strong>oretically <strong>an</strong>d empirically disent<strong>an</strong>gling how <strong>the</strong>interaction between particular combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms <strong>an</strong>d descriptive social normsdrives employee decisions. Although researchers have begun to recognize <strong>the</strong> <strong>interactions</strong> between<strong>the</strong> economic <strong>an</strong>d social structure <strong>of</strong> firms, prior literature has especially considered <strong>the</strong> influence <strong>of</strong>different characteristics <strong>of</strong> single formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms such as <strong>the</strong> framing, strength, or intentionality(Christ et al. 2010, Christ 2010; Coletti et al. 2005). However, while it is well-documented thatemployees are subject to multiple formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms when making decisions, <strong>the</strong> influence <strong>of</strong>characteristics <strong>of</strong> combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms has never been contemplated. Broadening <strong>the</strong>scope to combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms c<strong>an</strong> also explain <strong>the</strong> contradictions in previous researchabout <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms <strong>an</strong>d descriptive social norms for employee decisionmaking.In a broader perspective, our study also adds to <strong>the</strong> debate between sociologists, whichemphasize <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> social norms, <strong>an</strong>d economists, which emphasize <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>economic structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm (i.e. <strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> various formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms).Our study also adds to recent research in accounting which shows that conformity todescriptive social norms is driven by <strong>the</strong> implemented formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms. While Tayler <strong>an</strong>dBloomfield (2011) shows that <strong>the</strong> absence or presence <strong>of</strong> a formal mech<strong>an</strong>ism determinesconformity to descriptive social norms because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> different personal norms that are activated,we show that alignment <strong>of</strong> a combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms with <strong>the</strong> firm’s interest determines<strong>the</strong> saliency <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms <strong>an</strong>d thus <strong>the</strong> conformity to <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms.This research is also import<strong>an</strong>t to m<strong>an</strong>agers <strong>an</strong>d account<strong>an</strong>ts who design <strong>an</strong>d implementformal mech<strong>an</strong>isms <strong>an</strong>d c<strong>an</strong> provide <strong>the</strong> impetus for a ch<strong>an</strong>ge in <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms. Asfirms <strong>of</strong>ten implement various formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms <strong>an</strong>d are <strong>of</strong>ten involved in ch<strong>an</strong>ge processes, it isnot unlikely that <strong>the</strong>y will end up with a combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms that is not aligned with6


<strong>the</strong> firm’s interest. Our evidence that employee decisions are more in line with <strong>the</strong> firm’s bestinterest if descriptive social norms promote intra-firm cooperation emphasizes <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong>investing in developing close relationships between <strong>the</strong> different departments <strong>an</strong>d business-units.However, our study also shows that investing in descriptive social norms that promote intra-firmcooperation c<strong>an</strong> never correct for a misaligned combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms. Thus, our studyimplies that m<strong>an</strong>agers c<strong>an</strong> increase <strong>the</strong> extent to which employees act in <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest bypaying more attention (<strong>an</strong>d investing more money) to <strong>the</strong> alignment <strong>of</strong> all <strong>the</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>ismswith <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest.Finally, our research c<strong>an</strong> be import<strong>an</strong>t for future <strong>experimental</strong> <strong>an</strong>d non-<strong>experimental</strong>research about <strong>the</strong> influence <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms <strong>an</strong>d descriptive social norms on employeebehavior. Although our experiment m<strong>an</strong>ipulates whe<strong>the</strong>r combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms arealigned with <strong>the</strong> firm’s interest, <strong>the</strong> psychological <strong>the</strong>ory we rely on states that <strong>the</strong> perception <strong>of</strong>ambiguity is sufficient for making <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms more salient <strong>an</strong>d increasing <strong>the</strong>reli<strong>an</strong>ce on <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms. As survey research <strong>of</strong>ten has to rely on perceptions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>irrespondents, survey researchers c<strong>an</strong> use our findings to develop <strong>an</strong>d validate new surveyinstruments about <strong>the</strong> perception <strong>of</strong> ambiguity that is sent out by combinations <strong>of</strong> formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms in order to extent current <strong>the</strong>ory about <strong>the</strong> role <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms <strong>an</strong>d descriptivesocial norms.II.THEORY AND HYPOTHESES2.1 Misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms <strong>an</strong>d employee decisionsFirms are a bundling <strong>of</strong> different entities (i.e. individuals, departments or business units)from which <strong>the</strong> decisions <strong>an</strong>d actions should be coordinated in order to increase perform<strong>an</strong>ce(Jensen <strong>an</strong>d Meckling 1976). As <strong>the</strong> interests <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> entities <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> firm <strong>of</strong>ten diverge, <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ttask <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> m<strong>an</strong>ager is to develop <strong>an</strong> economic structure so that <strong>the</strong> different entities work toge<strong>the</strong>r<strong>an</strong>d take decisions that are in <strong>the</strong> best interest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm. Typically, <strong>the</strong> firm’s economic structureconsists <strong>of</strong> multiple formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms that c<strong>an</strong> be classified in two broad categories: incentivesystems <strong>an</strong>d information (Milgrom <strong>an</strong>d Roberts 1992).Previous studies have emphasized <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t role <strong>of</strong> incentives for obtaining coordination<strong>an</strong>d cooperation between interdependent entities. Bushm<strong>an</strong> et al. (1995), for inst<strong>an</strong>ce, shows thataggregate perform<strong>an</strong>ce measures, which are measured at <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm instead <strong>of</strong> at <strong>the</strong> level<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> entity, increase firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce when interdependencies between entities increases. Scott7


<strong>an</strong>d Tiessen (1999) comes to similar conclusions when investigating <strong>the</strong> relationship between <strong>the</strong>weight <strong>of</strong> team perform<strong>an</strong>ce in total compensation <strong>of</strong> team members <strong>an</strong>d team perform<strong>an</strong>ce.Analyzing compensation <strong>of</strong> medical group practices, Pizzini (2010) finds that <strong>the</strong> productive benefitsinduced by group incentives <strong>of</strong>fset reductions in output associated with free-riding <strong>an</strong>d effortdevoted to monitoring.Information is <strong>an</strong> equally import<strong>an</strong>t mech<strong>an</strong>ism to achieve cooperation between differententities. Although modern information systems make it possible to provide decision-makers withinformation on a timely basis, it is also import<strong>an</strong>t that <strong>the</strong> information is underst<strong>an</strong>dable for <strong>the</strong>decision-maker in order to make <strong>the</strong> decision-maker aware <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> his decisions on o<strong>the</strong>rentities <strong>an</strong>d on firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce. Rowe et al. (2008), for inst<strong>an</strong>ce, provides field evidence whichshows that <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> technical accounting jargon in summary reports about firm perform<strong>an</strong>ceinitiates competition ra<strong>the</strong>r th<strong>an</strong> cooperation between different entities. Wouters et al. (2008) alsodemonstrates that monetary qu<strong>an</strong>tification <strong>of</strong> differences between <strong>the</strong> available options, which is acore characteristic <strong>of</strong> accounting information, improves cross-functional decision-making <strong>an</strong>d leadsto a decision that is in <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest (Carru<strong>the</strong>rs <strong>an</strong>d Espel<strong>an</strong>d 1991). Thus, underst<strong>an</strong>dableinformation about <strong>the</strong> consequences <strong>of</strong> a decision facilitates <strong>the</strong> decision-maker to take into account<strong>the</strong>se consequences <strong>an</strong>d makes it more likely that <strong>the</strong> decision-maker chooses <strong>the</strong> option that is in<strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest.In <strong>the</strong> current study, we explicitly recognize that decisions <strong>of</strong> employees are shaped bymultiple formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms in general <strong>an</strong>d by incentive <strong>an</strong>d information systems in particular. Themain implication <strong>of</strong> broadening <strong>the</strong> scope to multiple formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms is that combinations <strong>of</strong>formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms c<strong>an</strong> be ei<strong>the</strong>r aligned or misaligned with <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest. A combination<strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms is aligned if all formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms instigate employees to act in <strong>the</strong> bestinterest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm. If not all formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms motivate or enable employees to act in <strong>the</strong> firm’sbest interest, <strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms is misaligned. Although misalignedcombinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms are not consistent with equilibrium assumptions, employees are<strong>of</strong>ten confronted with misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms. A major reason for <strong>the</strong>existence <strong>of</strong> misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms is <strong>the</strong> nearly continuous involvement inch<strong>an</strong>ge processes which inevitably implies that <strong>the</strong> various parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economic structure are not inline with <strong>the</strong> firm’s objective function (Jorgensen <strong>an</strong>d Messner 2009). Ano<strong>the</strong>r reason is that firms<strong>of</strong>ten consciously decide to focus on one particular formal mech<strong>an</strong>ism as <strong>the</strong>y believe that thismech<strong>an</strong>ism has <strong>the</strong> biggest impact on employee behavior.Misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms provide employees with mixed cues abouthow <strong>the</strong>y are expected to behave. While firms with misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms8


<strong>of</strong>ten have a well-specified corporate objective function, <strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>ismsdoes not guide employees in how <strong>the</strong>y have to make trade-<strong>of</strong>fs between departmental <strong>an</strong>d firmperform<strong>an</strong>ce (Jensen 2001). It has been well established in psychology that <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> mixedcues instigates individuals to give priority to <strong>the</strong>ir own interest at <strong>the</strong> disadv<strong>an</strong>tage <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> interest <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> group (Kramer 1999; Gaertner 2002; Rowe 2004). Similarly, we expect that <strong>the</strong> degree to whichemployees will act in <strong>the</strong> best interest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm will be lower in case <strong>of</strong> misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong>formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms compared to aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms. Thus, our firstprediction is as follows:H1: Misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms will lead to a lower degree <strong>of</strong> employeedecisions that are in <strong>the</strong> best interest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm compared to aligned combinations <strong>of</strong>formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms.2.2 The interactive effect between social norms <strong>an</strong>d combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>ismsThe full architecture <strong>of</strong> a firm is broader th<strong>an</strong> <strong>the</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms. Descriptive socialnorms, which describe how things are usually done within a firm, are also <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>firm <strong>an</strong>d have <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t influence on employee behavior. 2 With respect to cooperation betweendifferent departments or business units, descriptive social norms <strong>of</strong> a firm are generally situatedbetween <strong>the</strong> two ends <strong>of</strong> a continuum (i.e. high focus on intra-firm cooperation <strong>an</strong>d higherimport<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce compared to departmental perform<strong>an</strong>ce versus low focus on intrafirmcooperation <strong>an</strong>d higher import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> departmental perform<strong>an</strong>ce compared to firmperform<strong>an</strong>ce). 3 In order to obtain a situation in which intra-firm cooperation is “<strong>the</strong> way how thingsare done here”, comp<strong>an</strong>ies <strong>of</strong>ten invest a lot <strong>of</strong> money in social events <strong>an</strong>d teambuilding events.Although <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> such events for establishing intra-firm cooperation has been recognized,<strong>the</strong> question how <strong>the</strong>se descriptive social norms interact with different combinations <strong>of</strong> formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms has not been investigated yet.2 Social norms are <strong>of</strong>ten considered as a single construct. However, psychology literature makes a distinction betweendescriptive social norms, which refer to perceptions what is done, <strong>an</strong>d injunctive norms, which refer to perceptions <strong>of</strong> whatought to be done (Goldstein <strong>an</strong>d Cialdini 2010). As we w<strong>an</strong>t to refer to <strong>the</strong> way how things are actually done in <strong>an</strong>org<strong>an</strong>ization, which is not always equal to <strong>the</strong> way how it should be done, we will explicitly refer to descriptive socialnorms.3 Note that for some firms intra-firm cooperation is not part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir strategy. Typically, entities within <strong>the</strong>se firms are notinterdependent from each o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>an</strong>d firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce is maximized when each department or business unit focuses onmaximizing its own perform<strong>an</strong>ce. Our study does not focus on such firms.9


Researchers in psychology have paid enormous attention to <strong>the</strong> influence <strong>of</strong> descriptivesocial norms on behavior <strong>of</strong> individuals. Asch (1951), for inst<strong>an</strong>ce, shows that individuals agree with<strong>the</strong> wrong <strong>an</strong>swers <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r members <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir group <strong>an</strong>d that this effect is streng<strong>the</strong>ned when<strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r group members are un<strong>an</strong>imous <strong>an</strong>d show greater discomfort with deviations from <strong>the</strong>irun<strong>an</strong>imous <strong>an</strong>swer. In a more recent study, Goldstein et al. (2008) finds that hotel guests complymore with <strong>the</strong> towel-reuse rate <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hotel guests who had previously stayed in <strong>the</strong>ir roomth<strong>an</strong> with <strong>the</strong> towel-reuse rates <strong>of</strong> reference groups that are considered to be import<strong>an</strong>t <strong>an</strong>dpersonally me<strong>an</strong>ingful to <strong>the</strong> hotel guests. Also <strong>an</strong>alytical researchers have begun to incorporatesocial norms in <strong>the</strong>ir models <strong>an</strong>d find that behavior deviates from <strong>the</strong> behavior that c<strong>an</strong> be expectedwithout incorporating <strong>the</strong> social norms (Fisher <strong>an</strong>d Huddart 2008).Previous research has been inconclusive about <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economic structure<strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms for employee decisions. Maltz <strong>an</strong>d Kohli (1996), for inst<strong>an</strong>ce, findsthat formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms are more import<strong>an</strong>t th<strong>an</strong> <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms in directing employeedecisions, while An<strong>an</strong>d et al. (2009) <strong>an</strong>d Cousins et al. (2009) observe that <strong>the</strong> reverse is true. Priorstudies <strong>of</strong>ten consider formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms as one coherent construct or assume that different formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms are always aligned with <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest (Doerr et al. 1996). Thus, prior studiesfail to incorporate that combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms c<strong>an</strong> be ei<strong>the</strong>r aligned or misaligned,which is <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t characteristic <strong>of</strong> combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms (Roberts 2004).We predict <strong>an</strong> interactive effect between combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms <strong>an</strong>ddescriptive social norms. Recall that misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms provideemployees with mixed cues about how <strong>the</strong>y are expected to behave. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, misalignedcombinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms lead to <strong>an</strong> ambiguous situation. Theory in social psychologyposits that individuals are most likely to use <strong>the</strong> evidence <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r’s behavior to decide about <strong>the</strong>most effective course <strong>of</strong> action when <strong>the</strong> situation is novel, ambiguous or uncertain (Cialdini <strong>an</strong>dTrost 1998; Sherif <strong>an</strong>d Murphy 1936; Deutsch <strong>an</strong>d Gerrard 1955). Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>tpostulate <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> focus <strong>the</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> normative conduct is that norms are likely to influence behaviordirectly to <strong>the</strong> extent that it is salient (Cialdini et al. 1990; Goldstein <strong>an</strong>d Cialdini 2010; Kallgren et al.2000). Accordingly, misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms will lead to ambiguity that willmake <strong>the</strong> firm’s descriptive social norms a more salient source <strong>of</strong> information. Therefore, we expectthat <strong>the</strong> influence <strong>of</strong> descriptive social norms on employee decision-making will be larger whencombinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms are misaligned compared to aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms.10


Our <strong>the</strong>oretical reasoning assumes that employees will first consider <strong>the</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms<strong>an</strong>d only consult <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms when <strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms ismisaligned. A decision-making strategy in which <strong>the</strong> decision-maker begins by identifying <strong>the</strong> mostimport<strong>an</strong>t dimension <strong>an</strong>d only considers o<strong>the</strong>r dimensions if <strong>the</strong> first dimension does not lead to aclear decision is called a lexicographic decision-making strategy. Such a strategy is <strong>of</strong>ten used indecisions that have multiple dimensions (Plous 1993). The assumption that <strong>the</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>ismsare <strong>the</strong> most import<strong>an</strong>t dimension is consistent with Messick (1999) who posits that <strong>the</strong> underlyingeconomic structure <strong>of</strong> a situation is <strong>the</strong> most import<strong>an</strong>t cue to categorize <strong>the</strong> situation <strong>an</strong>d todetermine appropriate behavior. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, individuals that enter a firm are <strong>of</strong>ten first informedabout <strong>the</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms by me<strong>an</strong>s <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir contract or during information meetings about <strong>the</strong>working procedures.Thus, employees confronted with a misaligned combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms will beconfused about <strong>the</strong> expected behavior <strong>an</strong>d look for a more solid base for decision-making. This willmake <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms more salient <strong>an</strong>d a more import<strong>an</strong>t driver <strong>of</strong> employee behavior.Conversely, it is less likely that employees confronted with aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms will be confused <strong>an</strong>d this will restrain <strong>the</strong>m from consulting <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms.This results in <strong>the</strong> following hypo<strong>the</strong>sis:H2: The influence <strong>of</strong> descriptive social norms on <strong>the</strong> degree to which employee decisions arein <strong>the</strong> best interest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm will be larger for aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>ismsth<strong>an</strong> for misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>ismsH1 <strong>an</strong>d H2 are graphically represented in Figure 1. As predicted by H1, <strong>the</strong> degree to whichemployee decisions are in <strong>the</strong> best interest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm is lower when <strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms is misaligned compared to aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms. Following H2,<strong>the</strong> variation in descriptive social norms will lead to a difference between misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong>formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms but not between aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms.Insert Figure 1 About Here11


III.EXPERIMENTAL DESIGN3.1 Particip<strong>an</strong>ts <strong>an</strong>d ProcedureWe recruited 277 students from <strong>an</strong> undergraduate m<strong>an</strong>agement accounting class <strong>of</strong> a largeWest-Europe<strong>an</strong> university to participate in a computer-based experiment. 64 (36) percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>particip<strong>an</strong>ts were male (female) <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> average age was 20.5 years. Particip<strong>an</strong>ts receive a coursecredit for participating in <strong>the</strong> experiment <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong>y could win film tickets based on <strong>the</strong>ir perform<strong>an</strong>ceon <strong>the</strong> task. In Section 3.3 we will explain how particip<strong>an</strong>ts could win film tickets.We use a 3 (Combination <strong>of</strong> Formal Mech<strong>an</strong>isms) X 2 (Descriptive Social Norms) betweensubjects<strong>experimental</strong> design to test our hypo<strong>the</strong>ses. By m<strong>an</strong>ipulating <strong>the</strong> incentive system <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong>information system such that <strong>the</strong>y are ei<strong>the</strong>r focused on improving firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce ordepartmental perform<strong>an</strong>ce, we c<strong>an</strong> form three different combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms. Thefirst (second) combination has <strong>an</strong> incentive system that is focused on improving departmental (firm)perform<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> information system that is focused on improving firm (departmental)perform<strong>an</strong>ce. So, <strong>the</strong> first two combinations are misaligned combinations. The third combination has<strong>an</strong> incentive system <strong>an</strong>d information system that are both focused on improving firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce(i.e. aligned combination).At <strong>the</strong> beginning <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> experiment, particip<strong>an</strong>ts are r<strong>an</strong>domly assigned to one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> sixconditions. The experiment consists <strong>of</strong> three main parts. In <strong>the</strong> first part, particip<strong>an</strong>ts read a scenarioin which <strong>the</strong> incentive system, <strong>the</strong> information system <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms areexplained. The <strong>experimental</strong> scenario was explained over different screens <strong>an</strong>d subjects could read<strong>the</strong> information on each screen as long as <strong>the</strong>y c<strong>an</strong> but <strong>the</strong>y could not go back to earlier screens.Based on this scenario, particip<strong>an</strong>ts had to take decisions in <strong>the</strong> second part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> experiment. Thethird part consists <strong>of</strong> <strong>an</strong> ex-post questionnaire.3.2 Experimental TaskSubjects acted as purchasing m<strong>an</strong>agers making supplier selections for a virtual firm thatproduces parquet floors <strong>an</strong>d sells <strong>the</strong>m to <strong>the</strong> final customer. As <strong>the</strong> goods <strong>an</strong>d services delivered bysuppliers influence all <strong>the</strong> departments <strong>of</strong> a comp<strong>an</strong>y as well as <strong>the</strong> satisfaction <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> finalcustomers, supplier selections are a good example <strong>of</strong> <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t decision that influences firmperform<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d requires cooperation between different departments (Heikkilä 2002; Sheth et al.2009). The scenario mentioned that <strong>the</strong> strategy <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> current CEO emphasizes <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong>intra-firm cooperation to increase firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce. It was fur<strong>the</strong>r explained that <strong>the</strong> current12


supplier <strong>of</strong> wood, which is <strong>the</strong> most import<strong>an</strong>t component <strong>of</strong> parquet floors <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>tdetermin<strong>an</strong>t <strong>of</strong> customer satisfaction, has stopped <strong>the</strong> production <strong>of</strong> wood for parquet floors. Inorder to make <strong>the</strong> <strong>experimental</strong> task not overly complex, it was told to <strong>the</strong> particip<strong>an</strong>ts that <strong>the</strong>overall perform<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> a supplier is based on two metrics: <strong>the</strong> total costs <strong>of</strong> a supplier <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong>revenue-generating possibilities <strong>of</strong> a supplier. The total costs <strong>of</strong> a supplier refer to all <strong>the</strong> costs that asupplier causes within <strong>the</strong> firm such as purchasing cost, costs <strong>of</strong> waste, storage costs <strong>an</strong>dadministrative costs. 4 The revenue-generating possibilities <strong>of</strong> a supplier refer to <strong>the</strong> influence asupplier has on customer satisfaction <strong>an</strong>d thus on <strong>the</strong> revenues <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm to which <strong>the</strong> supplierdelivers his goods <strong>an</strong>d services. Although suppliers were traditionally evaluated on <strong>the</strong> total coststhat <strong>the</strong>y cause in <strong>the</strong> buying firm, comp<strong>an</strong>ies are increasingly aware <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> fact that suppliers alsoc<strong>an</strong> generate revenues if <strong>the</strong> characteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> goods <strong>an</strong>d services <strong>the</strong>y deliver match withcustomer preferences (Pl<strong>an</strong>k <strong>an</strong>d Ferrin 2002). Consequently, in order to select a supplier thatoptimizes firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce, purchasing m<strong>an</strong>agers have to make a trade-<strong>of</strong>f between <strong>the</strong> total coststhat a supplier causes <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> revenues that he generates (Wouters et al. 2005). To focus subjects’attention on <strong>the</strong> trade-<strong>of</strong>f between <strong>the</strong> total costs <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> revenue-generating possibilities, <strong>the</strong> intrafirmcooperation is limited to cooperation between <strong>the</strong> purchasing department, which <strong>of</strong>tencalculates <strong>the</strong> total costs <strong>of</strong> a supplier, <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> marketing department, which has a good idea aboutcustomer preferences <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> a new supplier on <strong>the</strong> firm’s revenues (Ivens et al. 2009). Itis import<strong>an</strong>t to mention that subjects in all <strong>the</strong> conditions receive <strong>the</strong> same information about <strong>the</strong>total costs. Specifically, for each supplier, <strong>the</strong>y all receive one number that reflects <strong>the</strong> total costs <strong>of</strong>that particular supplier. Our m<strong>an</strong>ipulation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> information system varies <strong>the</strong> way in which <strong>the</strong>revenue-generating possibilities <strong>of</strong> a supplier are represented. This will be explained in Section 3.3 <strong>of</strong>this study.After reading <strong>the</strong> scenario, subjects had to make six supplier selections. Each supplierselection was presented on one screen. Subjects could take as much time as <strong>the</strong>y w<strong>an</strong>t to make adecision but once a final decision was made, <strong>the</strong>y could not ch<strong>an</strong>ge <strong>the</strong>ir decision <strong>an</strong>ymore. To avoidorder effects, <strong>the</strong> sequence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> six supplier selections was r<strong>an</strong>domized. Subjects receivedinformation about <strong>the</strong> total costs <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> revenue-generating possibilities for each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two newsuppliers as well as for <strong>the</strong> current supplier. To avoid that <strong>the</strong> results are driven by <strong>the</strong> movement <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> total costs towards <strong>the</strong> current supplier, we differed <strong>the</strong> six supplier selections with respect to<strong>the</strong> movement <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total costs towards <strong>the</strong> current supplier. 54 The total costs <strong>of</strong> a supplier are similar to <strong>the</strong> Total Cost <strong>of</strong> Ownership <strong>of</strong> a supplier (Degraeve <strong>an</strong>d Roodho<strong>of</strong>t 2001).However, to avoid <strong>an</strong>y connotations with this technique, we do not label <strong>the</strong> total costs <strong>of</strong> a supplier as <strong>the</strong> ‘Total Cost <strong>of</strong>Ownership’.5 In two supplier selections, <strong>the</strong> total costs <strong>of</strong> both suppliers was higher compared to <strong>the</strong> total costs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> current supplier,in two supplier selections <strong>the</strong> total costs <strong>of</strong> both suppliers was lower compared to <strong>the</strong> total costs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> current supplier,13


For each supplier selection, subjects had to indicate <strong>the</strong>ir purchase intention for bothsuppliers by moving a slider over a horizontal bar. 6 By doing this, <strong>the</strong>y divided 100 points between<strong>the</strong> two new suppliers. The more points <strong>the</strong>y gave at a supplier, <strong>the</strong> higher <strong>the</strong>ir purchase intentionfor that supplier. If subjects were indifferent between both suppliers, <strong>the</strong>n both suppliers received 50points. Based on <strong>the</strong> subjects’ purchase intention, we constructed <strong>the</strong> dependent variable for ourstatistical tests. We tr<strong>an</strong>sformed <strong>the</strong> purchase intention to a scale from zero to 100 where zeroindicates <strong>the</strong> highest preference for <strong>the</strong> supplier that optimizes <strong>the</strong> perform<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> purchasingdepartment (i.e. supplier that causes <strong>the</strong> lowest total costs) <strong>an</strong>d 100 indicates <strong>the</strong> highest preferencefor <strong>the</strong> supplier that optimizes <strong>the</strong> perform<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm as a whole (i.e. supplier that optimizes<strong>the</strong> trade-<strong>of</strong>f between total costs <strong>an</strong>d revenue-generating possibilities). Thus, <strong>the</strong> higher <strong>the</strong> score forour dependent variable, <strong>the</strong> more subjects prefer a supplier that improves overall firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce.For our statistical tests, we take for each subject <strong>the</strong> average score <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> six supplier selections. Wewill call our dependent variable <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> firm-optimizing supplier selections.3.3 Experimental M<strong>an</strong>ipulationsThe incentive system is m<strong>an</strong>ipulated by providing particip<strong>an</strong>ts with <strong>an</strong> incentive to maximize<strong>the</strong> perform<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> purchasing department (i.e. minimize <strong>the</strong> total costs <strong>of</strong> a supplier) or tomaximize firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce (i.e. optimize <strong>the</strong> trade-<strong>of</strong>f between revenue-generating possibilities <strong>an</strong>dtotal costs). The department-based incentive formula is as follows:Total costs <strong>of</strong> a supplier – 10% <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> revenues that a supplier will generate if he isselected.Subjects with <strong>the</strong> department-based incentive were informed that <strong>the</strong>y should focus onminimizing <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir incentive formula (i.e. minimizing total costs <strong>of</strong> a supplier). The firmbasedincentive formula is as follows:<strong>an</strong>d in two supplier selections <strong>the</strong> total costs <strong>of</strong> one supplier was higher while <strong>the</strong> total costs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r supplier waslower compared to <strong>the</strong> current supplier. Within each group <strong>of</strong> two supplier selections, <strong>the</strong>re was one (one) supplierselection in which <strong>the</strong> total costs <strong>of</strong> both new suppliers were in a small (large) r<strong>an</strong>ge around <strong>the</strong> total costs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> currentsupplier.6 Marketing research has already shown that purchase intention scales are good predictors <strong>of</strong> real buying behavior (Wrigth<strong>an</strong>d MacRae 2008).14


Revenues that a supplier will generate if he is selected – Total costs <strong>of</strong> a supplierSubjects with <strong>the</strong> firm-based incentive were informed that <strong>the</strong>y should aim at maximizing<strong>the</strong>ir incentive formula (i.e. maximizing <strong>the</strong> contribution <strong>of</strong> a supplier to <strong>the</strong> overall firm pr<strong>of</strong>it). Them<strong>an</strong>ipulation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> incentive system is based on <strong>the</strong> distinction between local (i.e. departmentbased)<strong>an</strong>d aggregate (i.e. firm-based) perform<strong>an</strong>ce measures (Bushm<strong>an</strong> et al. 1995; Dumond 1994;Pl<strong>an</strong>k <strong>an</strong>d Ferrin 2002). It is fur<strong>the</strong>r import<strong>an</strong>t to mention that <strong>the</strong> way in which subjects could winfilm tickets is based on <strong>the</strong>ir perform<strong>an</strong>ce as calculated following <strong>the</strong>ir incentive system. Specifically,if one assigns more th<strong>an</strong> 50 points to <strong>the</strong> correct supplier based on <strong>the</strong> incentive system, <strong>the</strong>n oneearned that number <strong>of</strong> points. If one assigned more th<strong>an</strong> 50 points to <strong>the</strong> wrong supplier based on<strong>the</strong> incentive system, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> points that is assigned to <strong>the</strong> wrong supplier is subtractedfrom <strong>the</strong> total number <strong>of</strong> points. If one was indifferent between <strong>the</strong> two suppliers (i.e. both suppliers‘receive’ 50 points) <strong>the</strong>n one c<strong>an</strong>not win or lose points. So, only <strong>the</strong> majority <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> points that wereassigned to a supplier were taken into account to calculate <strong>the</strong> total number <strong>of</strong> points. In eachcondition, <strong>the</strong> four particip<strong>an</strong>ts with <strong>the</strong> highest number <strong>of</strong> points received a film ticket with a value<strong>of</strong> 8 EUR.The information system is m<strong>an</strong>ipulated by presenting <strong>the</strong> revenue-generating possibilities <strong>of</strong>a supplier in a monetary form or by me<strong>an</strong>s <strong>of</strong> r<strong>an</strong>kings. In both m<strong>an</strong>ipulations, subjects wereinformed that wood has three import<strong>an</strong>t characteristics <strong>of</strong> equal import<strong>an</strong>ce (durability, strength,<strong>an</strong>d mainten<strong>an</strong>ce) that c<strong>an</strong> influence customer satisfaction. If subjects receive information in amonetary form, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>y observe one number that indicates <strong>the</strong> revenues that <strong>the</strong> firm willgenerate if a particular supplier is chosen. For inst<strong>an</strong>ce, if <strong>the</strong> subject chooses for supplier A (B) <strong>the</strong>n<strong>the</strong> firm’s revenues will increase with 7 200 EUR (1 800 EUR). The r<strong>an</strong>kings indicate <strong>the</strong> relativeposition <strong>of</strong> a supplier for each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> three characteristics. Each supplier has a r<strong>an</strong>king (one, two orthree) for each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> characteristics <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> r<strong>an</strong>kings are constructed in such a way that <strong>the</strong> supplierthat generates <strong>the</strong> largest revenues outperforms <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r supplier in two out <strong>of</strong> threecharacteristics. As such, <strong>the</strong> monetary qu<strong>an</strong>tified information <strong>an</strong>d r<strong>an</strong>kings are economicallyequivalent <strong>an</strong>d should lead to <strong>the</strong> same supplier choice. Previous research has emphasized <strong>the</strong>import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> monetary qu<strong>an</strong>tification if <strong>the</strong> consequences <strong>of</strong> a decision are dispersed over differentdepartments or business units (Wouters et al. 2005; 2008). By monetary qu<strong>an</strong>tifying <strong>the</strong> differentconsequences, employees from different departments c<strong>an</strong> more easily compare <strong>the</strong> differentconsequences <strong>of</strong> a certain decision compared to <strong>the</strong> situation in which each department reports <strong>the</strong>consequences <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> decision in its own “l<strong>an</strong>guage”. Monetary qu<strong>an</strong>tification <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> variousconsequences <strong>of</strong> a decision should thus enable <strong>the</strong> employee to act in <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest.R<strong>an</strong>kings, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r h<strong>an</strong>d, should reflect <strong>the</strong> difficulties that employees encounter when <strong>the</strong>y15


eceive information in a typical departmental l<strong>an</strong>guage (Rowe et al. 2008) (see Appendix 1, P<strong>an</strong>el A). 78The descriptive social norms are m<strong>an</strong>ipulated by a scenario <strong>an</strong>d are based on <strong>the</strong> framework<strong>of</strong> Rousseau (1990). Rousseau (1990) argues that ‘<strong>the</strong> way how things are done’ in a firm has fivedetermin<strong>an</strong>ts: material artefacts (i.e. <strong>the</strong> physical m<strong>an</strong>ifestations <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> informal context), patterns <strong>of</strong>activity (i.e. decision-making, coordination <strong>an</strong>d communication mech<strong>an</strong>isms), behavioral norms (i.e.beliefs <strong>of</strong> employees regarding acceptable <strong>an</strong>d unacceptable behavior), values (i.e. priorities assignedto certain states or outcomes) <strong>an</strong>d fundamental assumptions. In <strong>the</strong> conditions in which <strong>the</strong>descriptive social norms (do not) promote intra-firm cooperation, we m<strong>an</strong>ipulated <strong>the</strong> fivedetermin<strong>an</strong>ts towards (low) high intra-firm cooperation. As such, descriptive social norms are ei<strong>the</strong>rdepartment-based or firm-based (see Appendix 1, P<strong>an</strong>el B).IV.RESULTS4.1 M<strong>an</strong>ipulation Checks <strong>an</strong>d Desriptive StatisticsTo ensure that <strong>the</strong> <strong>experimental</strong> m<strong>an</strong>ipulations provided appropriate contrasts between <strong>the</strong>different conditions, we asked questions about <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> total costs <strong>of</strong> a supplier in <strong>the</strong>incentive system, <strong>the</strong> underst<strong>an</strong>dability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> information about <strong>the</strong> revenue-generatingpossibilities, <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> cooperation between purchasing <strong>an</strong>d marketing. Results from t-testsindicate that <strong>the</strong> me<strong>an</strong>s <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> questions were signific<strong>an</strong>tly different between <strong>the</strong> conditions in <strong>the</strong>predicted direction (t=2.28, p


The descriptive statistics about <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> firm-optimizing supplier selections, <strong>the</strong> number<strong>of</strong> supplier selections with a purchase intention higher th<strong>an</strong> 50, <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> dispersion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> subjects’purchase intentions over <strong>the</strong> quintiles <strong>of</strong> our zero to 100 scale are reported in Table 1 <strong>an</strong>d 2. 9 Thecumulative distribution <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> subjects’ purchase intentions over <strong>the</strong> different quintiles is depicted inFigure 2. 10 This figure shows that <strong>the</strong> subjects’ purchase intentions are more equally dispersed over<strong>the</strong> different quintiles in case <strong>of</strong> misaligned combinations. For aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms, we observe a big jump in <strong>the</strong> cumulative distribution at <strong>the</strong> fifth quintile. This showsthat a high proportion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> subjects in <strong>the</strong>se conditions have a high preference for <strong>the</strong> supplier thatoptimizes firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce.Insert Table 1 <strong>an</strong>d 2 <strong>an</strong>d Figure 2 About here4.2 Hypo<strong>the</strong>sis 1Table 3 presents <strong>the</strong> results for our test <strong>of</strong> H1. H1 predicts that <strong>the</strong> degree to whichemployees take decisions in <strong>the</strong> best interest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm will be lower for misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong>formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms th<strong>an</strong> for aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms. Consistent with H1, wefind that <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> firm-optimizing supplier selections is signific<strong>an</strong>tly lower for misalignedcombinations th<strong>an</strong> for aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms (t=12.35, p


social norms (do not) promote intra-firm cooperation.) Our inferences do not ch<strong>an</strong>ge if we consider<strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> supplier selections with a purchase intention higher th<strong>an</strong> 50 as <strong>the</strong> dependentvariable (results not reported). Collectively, <strong>the</strong>se results provide strong support for H1 <strong>an</strong>d areconsistent with previous research (Gaertner et al. 2002; Rowe 2004).Insert Table 3 About Here4.3 Hypo<strong>the</strong>sis 2H2 considers <strong>the</strong> influence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms for different combinations <strong>of</strong>formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms. Specifically, H2 posits that <strong>the</strong> influence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms onemployee decision-making is higher for misaligned combinations th<strong>an</strong> for aligned combinations. Thisshould show up as <strong>an</strong> interaction effect between <strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms <strong>an</strong>ddescriptive social norms.Table 4, P<strong>an</strong>el A provides <strong>the</strong> results <strong>of</strong> <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>alysis <strong>of</strong> vari<strong>an</strong>ce (ANOVA) with combination <strong>of</strong>formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms <strong>an</strong>d descriptive social norms as <strong>the</strong> independent variables <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> firmoptimizingsupplier selections as <strong>the</strong> dependent variable. Results show a signific<strong>an</strong>t interaction <strong>of</strong>combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms <strong>an</strong>d descriptive social norms (F=4.20, p0.50) for descriptive social norms that (do not)promote intra-firm cooperation). This pattern <strong>of</strong> results is depicted in Figure 3. Analyses for <strong>the</strong>average number <strong>of</strong> supplier selections with a purchase intention higher th<strong>an</strong> 50 lead to <strong>the</strong> sameinferences (see Table 5 <strong>an</strong>d Figure 4).18


Overall, our results are consistent with <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>ory that misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms make <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms more salient which instigates employees to rely on<strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms to make <strong>the</strong>ir decisions.Insert Table 4 <strong>an</strong>d 5 About HereInsert Figure 3 <strong>an</strong>d 4 About HereIn order to rule out that our results are driven by a particular supplier selection, we did our<strong>an</strong>alyses for each supplier selection separately. Results <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se <strong>an</strong>alyses show that <strong>the</strong> interactioneffect between combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>ism <strong>an</strong>d descriptive social norms is signific<strong>an</strong>t in 4 out<strong>of</strong> 6 supplier selections. Results for <strong>the</strong> simple effects show that only one out <strong>of</strong> 18 simple effects isnot signific<strong>an</strong>t while all o<strong>the</strong>r simple effects are signific<strong>an</strong>t <strong>an</strong>d in <strong>the</strong> predicted direction.Import<strong>an</strong>tly, we never find a signific<strong>an</strong>t difference between <strong>the</strong> aligned combinations. We alsorepeat our <strong>an</strong>alyses for each period separately as <strong>the</strong> order <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> supplier selections is r<strong>an</strong>domizedin our experiment. Results show that <strong>the</strong> interaction effect is signific<strong>an</strong>t in 4 out <strong>of</strong> 6 supplierselections <strong>an</strong>d that <strong>the</strong> interaction effect is not signific<strong>an</strong>t in <strong>the</strong> first two periods. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, all<strong>the</strong> 18 simple effects are signific<strong>an</strong>t in <strong>the</strong> predicted direction. Collectively, <strong>the</strong> results for <strong>the</strong>different supplier selections <strong>an</strong>d for <strong>the</strong> different periods provide evidence that our results are notdriven by a particular supplier selection or a particular period.4.4 Additional AnalysesIn order to fur<strong>the</strong>r corroborate our results, we report <strong>the</strong> results <strong>of</strong> additional <strong>an</strong>alyses in thissection. First, we asked in <strong>the</strong> ex-post questionnaire questions about <strong>the</strong> underst<strong>an</strong>ding <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> way inwhich employees <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> virtual comp<strong>an</strong>y are rewarded (“I underst<strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> way in which I amrewarded by <strong>the</strong> comp<strong>an</strong>y”) <strong>an</strong>d about <strong>the</strong> easiness to take into account <strong>the</strong> information about <strong>the</strong>revenue-generating possibilities (“It was difficult to take into account <strong>the</strong> information about <strong>the</strong>revenue-generating possibilities”). Analyses <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> responses show that subjects better underst<strong>an</strong>d<strong>the</strong> way <strong>the</strong>y are rewarded (t=1.92, p


<strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> information system are both aligned with <strong>the</strong> firm’s best interest. These results providefur<strong>the</strong>r evidence that misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms lead to ambiguity.We also <strong>an</strong>alyzed <strong>the</strong> response times for making <strong>the</strong> six supplier selections. If our assumptionis correct that misaligned combinations lead to perceptions <strong>of</strong> conflict <strong>an</strong>d ambiguity <strong>the</strong>n we shouldobserve longer response times for misaligned combinations th<strong>an</strong> for aligned combinations (Smith<strong>an</strong>d Henry 1996). Comparing <strong>the</strong> total time that subjects need to make <strong>the</strong> supplier selections showthat <strong>the</strong> difference between conditions with aligned <strong>an</strong>d misaligned combinations is signific<strong>an</strong>t in <strong>the</strong>predicted direction (t=1.78, p0.40 for <strong>the</strong> question about confidence; F=0.89, p>0.45 for <strong>the</strong> question aboutbelief in own perform<strong>an</strong>ce). These <strong>an</strong>alyses show that <strong>the</strong> reli<strong>an</strong>ce on <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms isable to rule out <strong>the</strong> ambiguity that is caused by <strong>the</strong> misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms.The absence <strong>of</strong> <strong>an</strong>y difference between subjects that encounter descriptive social norms thatpromote intra-firm cooperation <strong>an</strong>d those that are confronted with descriptive social norms that donot promote intra-firm cooperation shows that compli<strong>an</strong>ce with ‘how things are done’ is <strong>an</strong>import<strong>an</strong>t determin<strong>an</strong>t for subjective feelings about <strong>the</strong> own behavior <strong>an</strong>d decisions (t=1.25, p>0.20for <strong>the</strong> question about confidence; t=1.01, p>0.30 for <strong>the</strong> question about belief in own perform<strong>an</strong>ce).V. CONCLUSIONSIn comp<strong>an</strong>ies that consider intra-firm cooperation as <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t determin<strong>an</strong>t <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>irperform<strong>an</strong>ce, employees have to make a lot <strong>of</strong> decisions that require a trade-<strong>of</strong>f between improving<strong>the</strong> perform<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> own department or business unit or improving overall firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce.Several decades <strong>of</strong> research has shown that <strong>the</strong> extent to which employees act in <strong>the</strong> firm’s bestinterest is driven by formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms as well as by <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm (Cialdini<strong>an</strong>d Trost 2010; Merch<strong>an</strong>t <strong>an</strong>d V<strong>an</strong> der Stede 2007; Milgrom <strong>an</strong>d Roberts 1992). Starting from <strong>the</strong>idea that employees are confronted with multiple formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms, our first prediction is thatmisaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms lower <strong>the</strong> degree to which employees act in <strong>the</strong>firm’s best interest. Relying on <strong>the</strong> finding from psychology that descriptive social norms are20


especially import<strong>an</strong>t in ambiguous situations, our second prediction is that descriptive social normswill be a more import<strong>an</strong>t driver <strong>of</strong> employee decisions for misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms th<strong>an</strong> for aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms. Our <strong>experimental</strong> results areconsistent with <strong>the</strong>se predictionsThis study contributes to <strong>the</strong> literature that examines <strong>the</strong> interaction between <strong>the</strong> economic<strong>an</strong>d social structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm. First, this study extends a recent stream <strong>of</strong> research that <strong>an</strong>alyzes <strong>the</strong>influence <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms on employee decisions. While prior studies examine variations <strong>of</strong> asingle formal mech<strong>an</strong>ism, this study takes into account that firms implement multiple formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms <strong>an</strong>d provides <strong>the</strong>ory <strong>an</strong>d evidence that employees confronted with misalignedcombinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms rely on <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms to make <strong>the</strong>ir decisions.Second, our study also contributes to recent studies about <strong>the</strong> influence <strong>of</strong> descriptive social normsin firms. Tayler <strong>an</strong>d Bloomfield (2011), for inst<strong>an</strong>ce, shows that conformity to descriptive socialnorms is determined by <strong>the</strong> type <strong>of</strong> personal norm that is activated (i.e. self-interested or sociallyinterestedpersonal norm) which is influenced by <strong>the</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong> a formal mech<strong>an</strong>ism. As inTayler <strong>an</strong>d Bloomfield (2011), our study shows that conformity to descriptive social norms is affectedby <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> a formal mech<strong>an</strong>ism. However, as we show that conformity to descriptive socialnorms is higher for misaligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms, we take <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms as a starting point <strong>an</strong>d vary <strong>the</strong> type <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms that are implemented.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, while Tayler <strong>an</strong>d Bloomfield (2011) took <strong>the</strong> approach <strong>of</strong> <strong>experimental</strong> economics tom<strong>an</strong>ipulate descriptive social norms, our study m<strong>an</strong>ipulates <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms in <strong>the</strong>tradition <strong>of</strong> psychology-based <strong>experimental</strong> work. Although direct comparisons between bothapproaches are difficult, each approach has its own adv<strong>an</strong>tages <strong>an</strong>d disadv<strong>an</strong>tages. Using bothapproaches c<strong>an</strong> improve <strong>an</strong>d refine our knowledge about <strong>the</strong> role <strong>of</strong> descriptive social norms.From a practical perspective, <strong>the</strong> results <strong>of</strong> this study are useful to m<strong>an</strong>agers <strong>an</strong>daccount<strong>an</strong>ts who are responsible for <strong>the</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms. On <strong>the</strong> one h<strong>an</strong>d,our results provide a justification for <strong>the</strong> huge amounts <strong>of</strong> money that firms invest in developinggood relationships between <strong>the</strong> various entities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm. As firms are <strong>of</strong>ten involved in ch<strong>an</strong>geprocesses or only focus on one type <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>ism, it is not unlikely that <strong>the</strong>y will end up witha misaligned combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms. Based on our findings, descriptive social norms thatpromote <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> intra-firm cooperation increase <strong>the</strong> extent to which employees act in <strong>the</strong>firm’s best interest in such situations. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r h<strong>an</strong>d, our results also show that descriptive socialnorms that promote intra-firm cooperation c<strong>an</strong> never correct for <strong>the</strong> ambiguity caused by amisaligned combination <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms. Thus, m<strong>an</strong>agers should reconsider <strong>the</strong> huge amounts<strong>of</strong> money that <strong>the</strong>y invest in developing good relationships between <strong>the</strong> various entities. Indeed,21


investing <strong>the</strong> same amount <strong>of</strong> money in <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms could signific<strong>an</strong>tly increase <strong>the</strong> degree to which employees’ decisions are in <strong>the</strong> firm’sbest interest. As <strong>the</strong> marginal costs <strong>an</strong>d marginal benefits <strong>of</strong> obtaining aligned combinations <strong>of</strong>formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms seem to be determined by industry <strong>an</strong>d firm characteristics, future survey <strong>an</strong>darchival research c<strong>an</strong> examine whe<strong>the</strong>r firms allocate money to <strong>the</strong> activities that should benefit<strong>the</strong>m <strong>the</strong> most given <strong>the</strong>ir marginal costs <strong>an</strong>d benefits <strong>of</strong> obtaining <strong>an</strong> aligned combination <strong>of</strong> formalmech<strong>an</strong>isms. 11The current study is subject to several limitations which provide avenues for future research.First, we only m<strong>an</strong>ipulate two formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms in our experiment to make our design not overlycomplex. As employees are subject to more th<strong>an</strong> two formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms, our experiment is asimplification <strong>an</strong>d future research c<strong>an</strong> investigate whe<strong>the</strong>r our results hold in more complexsituations. As our <strong>the</strong>ory does not specify <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms, we hypo<strong>the</strong>size that<strong>the</strong> addition <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms will not alter <strong>the</strong> results. Testing <strong>the</strong> boundary conditions <strong>of</strong> our<strong>the</strong>ory is <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t task for future research. Second, our <strong>experimental</strong> design does not allow us totest longitudinal consequences <strong>of</strong> aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms on <strong>the</strong> descriptivesocial norms. As Coletti et al. (2005) show that a strong formal mech<strong>an</strong>ism c<strong>an</strong> enh<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> informalrelationships between individuals, it would be interesting to investigate whe<strong>the</strong>r alignedcombinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms c<strong>an</strong> alter descriptive social norms that do not promote intrafirmcooperation. Such a finding would fur<strong>the</strong>r emphasize <strong>the</strong> import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>of</strong> developing alignedcombinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms.11 For some firms, <strong>the</strong> marginal benefits <strong>of</strong> obtaining aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms (i.e. <strong>the</strong> increase in <strong>the</strong>degree to which employees take decisions in <strong>the</strong> best interest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> org<strong>an</strong>ization) are higher th<strong>an</strong> <strong>the</strong> marginal costs (i.e.salaries paid to controllers that should develop aligned formal control mech<strong>an</strong>isms, costs for continuously monitoringwhe<strong>the</strong>r employees perceive ambiguity regarding <strong>the</strong> expected behavior). As a result, <strong>the</strong>se firms should invest indeveloping aligned combinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms. For o<strong>the</strong>r firms, <strong>the</strong> marginal costs <strong>of</strong> obtaining alignedcombinations <strong>of</strong> formal mech<strong>an</strong>isms are higher th<strong>an</strong> <strong>the</strong> marginal costs. These firms should invest in developing descriptivesocial norms that promote intra-firm cooperation.22


REFERENCESAn<strong>an</strong>d, G., P.T. Ward, <strong>an</strong>d M.V. Tatikonda. 2009. Role <strong>of</strong> Explicit <strong>an</strong>d Tacit Knowledge in Six SigmaProjects: <strong>an</strong> Empirical Examination <strong>of</strong> Differential Project Success. Journal <strong>of</strong> OperationsM<strong>an</strong>agement 27(6): 444-461.Ash, S.E. 1951. Effects <strong>of</strong> group pressure upon <strong>the</strong> modification <strong>an</strong>d distortion <strong>of</strong> judgment. In H.S.Guetzkow (Ed.), Groups, Leadership, <strong>an</strong>d Men, Carnegie Press Pittsburgh.Brown, D., <strong>an</strong>d M. Armstrong. 1999. Paying for contribution. Dover, NH: Kog<strong>an</strong> Page.Bushm<strong>an</strong>, R.M., R.J. Indjejiki<strong>an</strong>, <strong>an</strong>d A. Smith. 1995. Aggregate perform<strong>an</strong>ce measures in businessunit m<strong>an</strong>ager compensation: <strong>the</strong> role <strong>of</strong> intrafirm interdependencies. Journal <strong>of</strong> Accounting Research33(Supplement): 101-128.Carru<strong>the</strong>rs, B., <strong>an</strong>d W. Espel<strong>an</strong>d. 1991. Accounting for rationality: double-entry bookkeeping <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong>rhetoric <strong>of</strong> economic rationality. The Americ<strong>an</strong> Journal <strong>of</strong> Sociology 97(1): 31-69.Cialdini, R.B., R.R. Reno, <strong>an</strong>d C.A. Kallgren. 1990. A Focus Theory <strong>of</strong> Normative Conduct: Recycling <strong>the</strong>Concept <strong>of</strong> Norms to Reduce Littering in <strong>Public</strong> Places. Journal <strong>of</strong> Personality <strong>an</strong>d Social Psychology58(6): 1015-1026.Cialdini, R.B., <strong>an</strong>d M.R. Trost. 1998. Social influence: social norms, conformity, <strong>an</strong>d compli<strong>an</strong>ce. InD.T. Gilbert, S.T. Fiske, <strong>an</strong>d G. Lindzey (Eds.), The h<strong>an</strong>dbook <strong>of</strong> social psychology, Vol. 2: 151-192.Christ, M.H., K.L. Sedatole, <strong>an</strong>d K.L. Towry. 2010. Framing sticks as carrots: <strong>an</strong> <strong>experimental</strong><strong>investigation</strong> <strong>of</strong> control <strong>an</strong>d trust in agency relationships. Working Paper University <strong>of</strong> Georgia,Michig<strong>an</strong> State University, <strong>an</strong>d Emory University.Christ, M.H. 2010. An <strong>experimental</strong> <strong>investigation</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>interactions</strong> among intentions, reciprocity<strong>an</strong>d control. Working paper University <strong>of</strong> Georgia.Coletti, A.L., K.L. Sedatole, <strong>an</strong>d K.L. Towry. 2005. The effect <strong>of</strong> control systems on trust <strong>an</strong>dcooperation in collaborative environments. The Accounting Review 80(2): 477-500.23


Cousins, P.D., R.B. H<strong>an</strong>dfield, B. Lawson, <strong>an</strong>d K.J. Petersen. 2006. Creating supply chain relationalcapital: <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> formal <strong>an</strong>d informal socialization processes. Journal <strong>of</strong> OperationsM<strong>an</strong>agement 24: 851-863.Degraeve, Z., <strong>an</strong>d F. Roodho<strong>of</strong>t. 2001. A smarter way to buy. Harvard Business Review 79(6): 22-23.Deutsch, M., <strong>an</strong>d H.B. Gerard. 1955. A study <strong>of</strong> normative <strong>an</strong>d informational social influences uponindividual judgment. Journal <strong>of</strong> Abnormal <strong>an</strong>d Social Psychology 51: 629-636.Doerr, K.H., T.R. Mitchell, T.D. Klastorin, <strong>an</strong>d K.A. Brown. 1996. Impact <strong>of</strong> material flow policies <strong>an</strong>dgoals on job outcomes. Journal <strong>of</strong> Applied Psychology 81(2): 142-152.Dumond, E.J. 1994. Making best use <strong>of</strong> perform<strong>an</strong>ce measures <strong>an</strong>d perform<strong>an</strong>ce. InternationalJournal <strong>of</strong> Operations <strong>an</strong>d Production M<strong>an</strong>agement 14(9): 16-31.Fisher, P., <strong>an</strong>d S. Huddart. 2008. Optimal contracting with endogenous social norms. Americ<strong>an</strong>Economic Review 98: 1459-1475.Gaertner, L., C. Sedikides, J.L. Vevea, <strong>an</strong>d J. Iuzini. 2002. The “I”, <strong>the</strong> “we” <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> “when”: a meta<strong>an</strong>alysis<strong>of</strong> motivational primacy in self-definition. Journal <strong>of</strong> Personality <strong>an</strong>d Social Psychology 83:574-591.Galbraith, J.R. 2005. Designing <strong>the</strong> customer-centric org<strong>an</strong>isation, a guide to strategy, structure <strong>an</strong>dprocess. S<strong>an</strong> Fr<strong>an</strong>ciso: Jossey-Bass.Goldstein, N.J., R.B. Cialdini, <strong>an</strong>d V. Griskevicius. 2008. A room with a viewpoint: using social norms tomotivate environmental conservations in hotels. Journal <strong>of</strong> Consumer Research 35: 472-482.Goldstein, N.J., <strong>an</strong>d R.B. Cialdini. 2010. M<strong>an</strong>aging Normative Influences in Org<strong>an</strong>izations. In D. DeCremer, R. v<strong>an</strong> Dick, <strong>an</strong>d J.K. Murnigh<strong>an</strong> (Eds), Social Psychology <strong>an</strong>d Org<strong>an</strong>izations, Routledge.Heikkilä, J. 2002. From supply to dem<strong>an</strong>d chain m<strong>an</strong>agement: efficiency <strong>an</strong>d customer satisfaction.Journal <strong>of</strong> Operations M<strong>an</strong>agement 20: 747-767.24


Ivens, B.J., C. Pardo, <strong>an</strong>d A. Tunisini. 2009. Org<strong>an</strong>izing <strong>an</strong>d integrating marketing <strong>an</strong>d purchasing inbusiness markets: An introduction to <strong>the</strong> special issue, issues <strong>an</strong>d implications. Industrial MarketingM<strong>an</strong>agement 38: 851-856.Jensen, M.C., <strong>an</strong>d W.H. Meckling. 1976. Theory <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm: m<strong>an</strong>agerial behavior, agency costs <strong>an</strong>downership structure. Journal <strong>of</strong> Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Economics 3: 305-360.Jensen, M. 2001. Value maximization, stakeholder <strong>the</strong>ory, <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> corporate objective function.Journal <strong>of</strong> Applied Corporate Fin<strong>an</strong>ce 14(3): 8-21.Jorgensen, B., <strong>an</strong>d M. Messner. 2009. M<strong>an</strong>agement Control in New Product Development: TheDynamics <strong>of</strong> M<strong>an</strong>aging Flexibility <strong>an</strong>d Efficiency. Journal <strong>of</strong> M<strong>an</strong>agement Accounting Research 21: 99-124.Kallgren, C.A., R.R. Reno, <strong>an</strong>d R.B. Cialdini. 2000. A Focus Theory <strong>of</strong> Normative Conduct: When NormsDo <strong>an</strong>d Do not Affect Behavior. Personality <strong>an</strong>d Social Psychology Bulletin 26: 1002-1012.Kramer, R. 1999. Trust <strong>an</strong>d distrust in org<strong>an</strong>izations: emerging perspectives, enduring questions.Annual Review <strong>of</strong> Psychology 50: 569-598.Maltz, E., <strong>an</strong>d A.K. Kohli. 1996. Market Intelligence Dissemination Across Functional Boundaries.Journal <strong>of</strong> Marketing Research 33: 47-61.Merch<strong>an</strong>t, K., <strong>an</strong>d W.A. V<strong>an</strong> der Stede. 2007. M<strong>an</strong>agement Control Systems: Perform<strong>an</strong>ceMeasurement, Evaluation <strong>an</strong>d Incentives. Prentice Hall.Messick, D.M. 1999. Alternative logics for decision-making in social settings. Journal <strong>of</strong> EconomicBehavior & Org<strong>an</strong>ization 39(1): 11-28.Milgrom, P., <strong>an</strong>d J. Roberts. 1992. Economics, Org<strong>an</strong>ization & M<strong>an</strong>agement. Prentice Hall.Pizzini, M. 2010. Group-Based Compensation in Pr<strong>of</strong>essional Service Firms: An Empirical Analysis <strong>of</strong>Medical Group Practices. The Accounting Review 85(1): 343-380.25


Pl<strong>an</strong>k, R.E., <strong>an</strong>d B.G. Ferrin. 2002. How m<strong>an</strong>ufacturers value purchase <strong>of</strong>ferings. An exploratory study.Industrial Marketing M<strong>an</strong>agement 31: 457-465.Roberts, J. 2004. The Modern Firm: Org<strong>an</strong>izational Design for Perform<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d Growth. OxfordUniversity Press.Rom<strong>an</strong>, F.J. 2009. An <strong>an</strong>alysis <strong>of</strong> ch<strong>an</strong>ges to a team-based incentive pl<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d its effects onproductivity, product quality, <strong>an</strong>d absenteeism. Accounting, Org<strong>an</strong>izations <strong>an</strong>d Society 34: 589-618.Rowe, C. 2004. The effect <strong>of</strong> accounting report structure <strong>an</strong>d team structure on perform<strong>an</strong>ce incross-functional teams. The Accounting Review 79: 1153-1180.Rowe, C., J. Birnberg, <strong>an</strong>d M.D. Shields. 2008. Effects <strong>of</strong> org<strong>an</strong>isational process ch<strong>an</strong>ge onresponsibility accounting <strong>an</strong>d m<strong>an</strong>agers’revelations <strong>of</strong> private knowledge. Accounting, Org<strong>an</strong>izations<strong>an</strong>d Society 33(2-3): 164-198.Scott, T.W., <strong>an</strong>d P. Tiessen. 1999. Perform<strong>an</strong>ce measurement <strong>an</strong>d m<strong>an</strong>agerial teams. Accounting,Org<strong>an</strong>izations <strong>an</strong>d Society 24: 263-285.Sherif, M., <strong>an</strong>d G. Murphy. 1936. The Psychology <strong>of</strong> Social Norms. Harper & Bro<strong>the</strong>rs.Sheth, J.N., A. Sharma, <strong>an</strong>d G.R. Iyer. 2009. Why integrating purchasing with marketing is bothinevitable <strong>an</strong>d beneficial. Industrial Marketing M<strong>an</strong>agement 38: 865-871.Smith, E.R., <strong>an</strong>d S. Henry. 1996. An In-Group Becomes Part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Self: Response Time Evidence.Personality <strong>an</strong>d Social Psychology Bulletin 22(6): 635-642.Sprinkle, G. 2003. Perspectives on <strong>experimental</strong> research in m<strong>an</strong>agerial accounting. Accounting,Org<strong>an</strong>izations <strong>an</strong>d Society 28: 287-318.Tayler, W.B., <strong>an</strong>d R.J. Bloomfield. 2011. Norms, Conformity, <strong>an</strong>d Controls. Journal <strong>of</strong> AccountingResearch, Forthcoming.26


Wouters, M., J.C. Anderson, <strong>an</strong>d F. Wynstra. 2005. The adoption <strong>of</strong> total cost <strong>of</strong> ownership forsourcing decisions – a structural equations <strong>an</strong>alysis. Accounting, Org<strong>an</strong>izations <strong>an</strong>d Society 30: 167-191.Wouters, M., J.C. Anderson, J.A. Narus, <strong>an</strong>d F. Wynstra. 2008. Accountability for cost <strong>an</strong>dperform<strong>an</strong>ce in sourcing decisions for new product development projects. Journal <strong>of</strong> OperationsM<strong>an</strong>agement 27: 64-77.Wright, M., <strong>an</strong>d M. MacRae. 2007. Bias <strong>an</strong>d variability in purchase intention scales. Journal <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Academy <strong>of</strong> Marketing Science 35(4): 617-623.27


TABLE 1: Descriptive StatisticsTable 1 reports <strong>the</strong> me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d (st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation) for <strong>the</strong> two main dependent variables <strong>of</strong> this study: <strong>the</strong>degree <strong>of</strong> firm-optimizing supplier selections <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> supplier selections with a purchase intentionhigher th<strong>an</strong> 50. The degree <strong>of</strong> firm-optimizing supplier selections is calculated as <strong>the</strong> average <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> purchaseintention <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 6 supplier selections. The purchase intention for each supplier selection is scaled from 0 to 100<strong>an</strong>d a higher (lower) purchase intention indicates a higher preference for <strong>the</strong> supplier that optimizes firm(departmental) perform<strong>an</strong>ce. The number <strong>of</strong> supplier selections with a purchase intention higher th<strong>an</strong> 50indicates in how m<strong>an</strong>y supplier selections <strong>the</strong> particip<strong>an</strong>ts’ purchase intention is higher th<strong>an</strong> 50 (i.e. how m<strong>an</strong>ytimes <strong>the</strong> particip<strong>an</strong>ts have a preference for <strong>the</strong> supplier that optimizes firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce). A higher numberfor this dependent variable thus indicates a higher preference for <strong>the</strong> supplier that optimizes firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce.In Table 1, ‘Low’ refers to <strong>the</strong> conditions in which <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms do not promote intra-firmcooperation <strong>an</strong>d ‘High’ refers to <strong>the</strong> conditions in which <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms promote intra-firmcooperation.Degree <strong>of</strong> firm-optimizingsupplier selectionsNumber <strong>of</strong> SupplierSelections with a PurchaseIntention > 50Misaligned Formal Control Mech<strong>an</strong>ismsAligned Formal ControlMech<strong>an</strong>ismsDepartment-based IncentiveSystem + Firm-basedInformation SystemFirm-based Incentive System+ Department-basedInformation SystemFirm-based IncentiveSystem + Firm-basedInformation SystemLow High Low High Low High40.95(35.65)2.48(2.49)57.48(31.66)3.57(2.30)37.91(20.71)2.04(1.67)54.26(19.71)3.54(1.76)87.90(13.81)5.62(0.61)86.40(15.46)5.49(0.83)Number <strong>of</strong> Particip<strong>an</strong>ts 46 47 46 46 45 4728


TABLE 2: Quintile Distribution <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Degree <strong>of</strong> Firm-Optimizing Supplier SelectionsTable 2 reports <strong>the</strong> quintile distribution <strong>an</strong>d <strong>the</strong> (cumulative quintile distribution) <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> firmoptimizingsupplier selections for <strong>the</strong> different conditions. In Table 2, ‘Misaligned 1’ refers to <strong>the</strong> combination<strong>of</strong> a department-based incentive system <strong>an</strong>d a firm-based information system. ‘Misaligned 2’ refers to <strong>the</strong>combination <strong>of</strong> a firm-based incentive system <strong>an</strong>d a department-based information system. ‘Aligned’ refers to<strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> a firm-based incentive system <strong>an</strong>d a firm-based information system. ‘Low’ refers to <strong>the</strong>conditions in which <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms do not promote intra-firm cooperation <strong>an</strong>d ‘High’ refers to <strong>the</strong>conditions in which <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms promote intra-firm cooperation.HIGHLOWMisaligned 1Misaligned 2AlignedMisaligned 1Misaligned 2Aligned0-20 21-40 41-60 61-80 81-1000.220.170.020.210.38(0.22) (0.39) (0.41) (0.62)(1)0.180.180.080.330.22(0.18) (0.37) (0.45) (0.78)(1)0.040.040.010.160.76(0.04) (0.08) (0.09) (0.25)(1)0.450.130.030.160.25(0.45) (0.58) (0.60) (0.75)(1)0.320.260.100.230.08(0.32) (0.58) (0.68) (0.92)(1)0.010.030.030.170.75(0.01) (0.04) (0.08) (0.25)(1)29


Hypo<strong>the</strong>sis 1TABLE 3:Table 3 reports <strong>the</strong> results for Hypo<strong>the</strong>sis 1 for <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> firm-optimizing supplier selections. P<strong>an</strong>el A doesnot make a distinction between <strong>the</strong> two types <strong>of</strong> misaligned formal control mech<strong>an</strong>isms. In P<strong>an</strong>el B <strong>an</strong>d P<strong>an</strong>elC, a distinction between <strong>the</strong> two types <strong>of</strong> misaligned formal control mech<strong>an</strong>isms is made. Misaligned 1 refers to<strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> a department-based incentive system <strong>an</strong>d a firm-based information system. Misaligned 2refers to <strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> a firm-based incentive system <strong>an</strong>d a department-based information system.Aligned refers to <strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> a firm-based incentive system <strong>an</strong>d a firm-based information system. Eachp<strong>an</strong>el contains overall results (i.e. no distinction between descriptive social norms – conditions), <strong>an</strong>d results foreach descriptive social norm – condition separately.P<strong>an</strong>el A: Misaligned versus Aligned Formal Control Mech<strong>an</strong>ismsOverallDescriptive Social Normsthat Promote Intra-FirmCooperationDescriptive Social Normsthat Promote Intra-FirmCooperationMisaligned 47.70 55.89 39.42Aligned 87.13 86.40 87.90T-test 12.35 *** 7.32 *** 10.62 ***P<strong>an</strong>el B: Department-based Incentive System + Firm-based Information System Versus Aligned Formal ControlMech<strong>an</strong>ismsOverallDescriptive Social Normsthat Promote Intra-FirmCooperationDescriptive Social Normsthat Promote Intra-FirmCooperationMisaligned 1 49.30 57.48 40.95Aligned 87.13 86.40 87.90T-test 10.27 *** 6.01 *** 8.90 ***P<strong>an</strong>el C: Firm-based Incentive System + Department-based Information System Versus Aligned Formal ControlMech<strong>an</strong>ismsOverallDescriptive Social Normsthat Promote Intra-FirmCooperationDescriptive Social Normsthat Promote Intra-FirmCooperationMisaligned 2 46.08 54.26 37.91Aligned 87.13 86.40 87.90T-test 11.12 *** 6.64 *** 9.48 ***30


TABLE 4:Hypo<strong>the</strong>sis 2: Degree <strong>of</strong> Firm-Optimizing Supplier SelectionsTable 4 reports <strong>the</strong> results for Hypo<strong>the</strong>sis 2 for <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> firm-optimizing supplier selections as dependentvariable. P<strong>an</strong>el A contains <strong>the</strong> Anova-results. The simple effects <strong>of</strong> interest are reported in P<strong>an</strong>el B. ‘Low’ refersto <strong>the</strong> conditions in which <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms do not promote intra-firm cooperation <strong>an</strong>d ‘High’ refersto <strong>the</strong> conditions in which <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms promote intra-firm cooperation.P<strong>an</strong>el A: Anova resultsSource Df SS MS F p-valueModel 5 108,570.07 21,714.01 36.93


TABLE 5:Hypo<strong>the</strong>sis 2: Number <strong>of</strong> Supplier Selections with a Purchase Intention Higher th<strong>an</strong> 50Table 5 reports <strong>the</strong> results for Hypo<strong>the</strong>sis 2 for <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> supplier selections with a purchase intentionhigher th<strong>an</strong> 50. P<strong>an</strong>el A contains <strong>the</strong> Anova-results. The simple effects <strong>of</strong> interest are reported in P<strong>an</strong>el B. ‘Low’refers to <strong>the</strong> conditions in which <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms do not promote intra-firm cooperation <strong>an</strong>d ‘High’refers to <strong>the</strong> conditions in which <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms promote intra-firm cooperation.P<strong>an</strong>el A: Anova resultsSource Df SS MS F p-valueModel 5 511.24 102.25 33.12


FIGURE 1:Expected EffectsFigure 1 shows <strong>the</strong> expected effects based on Hypo<strong>the</strong>sis 1 <strong>an</strong>d Hypo<strong>the</strong>sis 2. Misaligned 1 refers to <strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> adepartment-based incentive system <strong>an</strong>d a firm-based information system. Misaligned 2 refers to <strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> a firmbasedincentive system <strong>an</strong>d a department-based information system. Aligned refers to <strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> a firm-basedincentive system <strong>an</strong>d a firm-based information system. ‘Low’ refers to <strong>the</strong> conditions in which <strong>the</strong> descriptive social normsdo not promote intra-firm cooperation <strong>an</strong>d ‘High’ refers to <strong>the</strong> conditions in which <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms promoteintra-firm cooperation.degree <strong>of</strong> firm-optimizingsupplier selectionshighlowmisaligned 1 misaligned 2 aligned33


FIGURE 2:Cumulative Quintile DistributionFigure 2 shows <strong>the</strong> cumulative quintile distribution <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> firm-optimizing supplier selections for <strong>the</strong>6 conditions. Misaligned 1 refers to <strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> a department-based incentive system <strong>an</strong>d a firm-basedinformation system. Misaligned 2 refers to <strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> a firm-based incentive system <strong>an</strong>d adepartment-based information system. Aligned refers to <strong>the</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> a firm-based incentive system <strong>an</strong>da firm-based information system. ‘Low’ refers to <strong>the</strong> conditions in which <strong>the</strong> descriptive social norms do notpromote intra-firm cooperation <strong>an</strong>d ‘High’ refers to <strong>the</strong> conditions in which <strong>the</strong> descriptive social normspromote intra-firm cooperation.10,90,80,70,60,50,40,30,20,100--20 21--40 41--60 61--80 81--100High - Misaligned 1High - Misaligned 2High - AlignedLow - Misaligned 1Low - Misaligned 2Low - Aligned34


FIGURE 3:Hypo<strong>the</strong>sis 2: Degree <strong>of</strong> Firm-Optimizing Supplier Selections1009080706050403020100misaligned 1 misaligned 2 alignedhighlow35


FIGURE 4:Hypo<strong>the</strong>sis 2: Number <strong>of</strong> Supplier Selections with a Purchase Intention Higher th<strong>an</strong> 5065432highlow10misaligned 1 misaligned 2 aligned36


APPENDIX 1P<strong>an</strong>el A: Information systemTotal cost informationRevenu-generating possibilitiesTotal cost Ch<strong>an</strong>ge in total cost Revenues Ch<strong>an</strong>ge in revenuesCurrent supplier 60 000 EUR 70 000 EURNew supplier I 64 200 EUR + 4 200 EUR 77 200 EUR + 7 200 EURNew supplier II 61 200 EUR + 1 200 EUR 71 800 EUR + 1 800 EUR1 Shaded areas are condition specific. In <strong>the</strong> conditions in which <strong>the</strong> information system should lead to<strong>the</strong> optimization <strong>of</strong> overall firm perform<strong>an</strong>ce, subjects receive <strong>the</strong> information in <strong>the</strong> shaded areas. In <strong>the</strong>conditions in which <strong>the</strong> information system should lead to <strong>the</strong> optimization <strong>of</strong> departmental perform<strong>an</strong>ce,subjects receive <strong>the</strong> information about revenue-generating possibilities as follows:Revenu-generating possibilitiesSupplier I Supplier II Current supplierDurability 1 2 3Strength 1 2 3Mainten<strong>an</strong>ce 2 1 3P<strong>an</strong>el B: Descriptive Social NormsLow intra-firm cooperation Informal element High intra-firm cooperationPurchasing <strong>an</strong>d marketing arelocated in a different building.Material artefacts Purchasing <strong>an</strong>d marketing are locatedin <strong>the</strong> same building.2 times a year, <strong>the</strong>re is a meeting todiscuss problems. However,everyone considered <strong>the</strong> meetingsas boring.Coordination <strong>an</strong>dCommunicationmech<strong>an</strong>ismsThere is a weekly meeting to discussproblems <strong>an</strong>d to search for solutions.There are less informal contactsbetween <strong>the</strong> purchasing <strong>an</strong>dmarketing department.Cross-functional collaboration is not<strong>the</strong> most import<strong>an</strong>t aspect in yourfirm. Everyone is convinced that afocus on <strong>the</strong> activities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> owndepartment will lead to goodresults.Your firm is founded by 1 m<strong>an</strong> whowas convinced that specializationon <strong>the</strong> tasks <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> own departmentis already difficult enough.Behavioral normsValuesFundamentalassumptionsThere are a lot <strong>of</strong> informal contactsbetween <strong>the</strong> purchasing <strong>an</strong>dmarketing department.Cross-functional collaboration isconsidered as fundamental to obtaingood results.Your firm is founded by 2 bro<strong>the</strong>rswho have always collaborated <strong>an</strong>dhave stimulated cross-functionalintegrations.37

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!