13.07.2015 Views

Do emotions matter? Coherent preferences under anchoring and ...

Do emotions matter? Coherent preferences under anchoring and ...

Do emotions matter? Coherent preferences under anchoring and ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

706 ECOLOGICAL ECONOMICS 66 (2008) 700– 711Table 1 – Estimation results of Bayesian bivariate modelsfor a naïve <strong>and</strong> anchored individual (posterior st<strong>and</strong>arddeviations in parentheses)Naïve model Anchored modelIntercept 18.9460(4.5615)EIS 12.9748(0.8970)Age −0.2461(0.0463)Log (KIL) 5.1005(1.7401)EDU 0.4274(0.1714)INC 0.0062(0.0018)β 1 β 2 β 1 β 20.7664(3.6249)15.0844(0.6515)−0.2005(0.0353)7.1897(1.3784)0.5997(0.1259)0.0030(0.0014)18.8234(4.4138)12.9463(0.8947)−0.2450(0.0446)5.0873(1.7373)0.4333(0.1683)0.0063(0.0018)0.7878(3.5954)15.0560(0.6486)−0.2006(0.0351)7.1883(1.3571)0.6005(0.1288)0.0030(0.0014)BID 1 – – – 0.2694(0.0379)σ1 13.0619 (0.5807) 13.0302 (0.5603)σ2 11.0802 (0.6310) 11.0647 (0.6313)σ21 70.4236 (8.2962) 59.6298 (10.3180)Mean WTP 19.18 [18.43, 19.98] 19.16 [18.37, 20.01]Marginal likelihood −1113.97 −1057.26by the number of kilometers to be rehabilitated in the policyprogram presented in the market construct.Table 1 shows the estimation results for the simultaneousequation model for two alternative assumptions. Under thenaïve assumption, we omit the bid price from the first response(B i 1 ). Here the <strong>anchoring</strong> effects are not modeled (Whitehead,2002). The second assumption explicitly considers the bid priceof the first question in the equation for the second response.Anchoring effects as induced by the first bid offered are relevantin this application, as is evident by the significance of the firstbid price in the second equation. This result has been obtainedin most applications of the double-bounded dichotomouschoice format (e.g. Green et al., 1998).The results in Table 1 show also the relevance of some otherexplanatory variables that are significant in explaining WTP atboth stages of the elicitation process. WTP rises with income(INC) <strong>and</strong> the years of education (EDU), while decreases with theage of the individual (AGE). The significance of these explanatoryvariables can be interpreted as giving support to the constructvalidity of the contingent valuation study that was designed tovalue the rehabilitation of a network of walking paths.But for our purposes, the main variables of interest in theoutput regression of the bivariate model are the emotionalintensity scale (EIS) <strong>and</strong> the logarithm of the number ofkilometers presented in the valuation task of the contingentvaluation scenario (KIL). 17 These variables are both significantat the 95% level, supporting the following two empiricalresults:logarithmic: when the number of kilometers of the walkingpaths network was increased, mean WTP also increased,but at a decreasing rate. Thus, the scope effect or theabsence of sensitivity to the dimensions of the good to bevalued can be rejected for this particular application.2. The emotional state of the individual played a significantrole on the elicited values of the environmental good inquestion. This relationship was positive, i.e. the higher theemotional state the large becomes WTP.Even though these variables are important for explainingWTP at an aggregate level, they can be also related to thedegree of <strong>anchoring</strong> which is likely to be found in theelicitation mechanism of the DBDC model. Thus, let usconsider the relationships between the <strong>anchoring</strong> effects<strong>and</strong> i) the scope effect, <strong>and</strong> ii) the state of emotional loadfacing the individual.4.1. Scope <strong>and</strong> <strong>anchoring</strong> effectsIn order to ascertain whether scope effects are also present forthe various <strong>anchoring</strong> bids utilized in the experiment, Table 2reports the mean WTP for the subsamples of the lowest <strong>and</strong>highest bids utilized in the first dichotomous choice question.It can be seen that the size of the walking paths network has asimilar influence on WTP across the lowest <strong>and</strong> highest bidsoffered to the individuals. This result is similar to the onefound by Ariely et al. (2003) in what these authors called“coherent arbitrariness”. That is, although <strong>preferences</strong> arelikely to be influenced by initial anchors or bids, they can becoherent in economic terms for the different dimensions ofthe good to be valued. 18However, the scope effect giving support to the coherenceof <strong>preferences</strong> <strong>under</strong> <strong>anchoring</strong>, could be dependent on theemotional status of the individual facing the task of valuingdifferent dimension of a given good. Thus, this potentialrelationship would raise the need to consider the role of<strong>emotions</strong> in both the <strong>anchoring</strong> <strong>and</strong> scope effects.4.2. Emotional load <strong>and</strong> <strong>anchoring</strong> effectsThe extent of the <strong>anchoring</strong> effects can be also influenced bythe emotional status of the individual. In general, thishypothesis implies that the cognitive aspects of the valuationtask, i.e. the commonly found recurrence to some anchor inorder to base a valuation response, can be influenced by theemotional aspects involved. As can be seen in Table 3, theparameter of the <strong>anchoring</strong> effect η i is related with the level ofemotional load posed by the individual in the valuation task.The relationship between the anchor parameter η i <strong>and</strong> theEIS is depicted in Fig. 2. Low <strong>and</strong> high values of EIS correspondwith significantly high levels of <strong>anchoring</strong>. This relationship is1. There was significant sensitivity of WTP to the size of theenvironmental good being offered. This relationship was17 After testing for the validity <strong>and</strong> reliability of the EIS, the PCAreported that a model with only one factor provide the mostsatisfactory solution (e.g. reported Cronbach's alpha was 0.92).18 Ariely et al. (2003) found coherent <strong>preferences</strong> within individuals,i.e. by asking an individual about various dimensions of agiven good. Since we used split samples for the sizes of thewalking path network, our results can be interpreted as supportingcoherent <strong>preferences</strong> at an aggregate level, rather than at anindividual one, i.e. at a social welfare function rather than atindividual utility functions.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!