08.08.2015 Views

price stabilization measures and its effects on - Philippine Institute ...

price stabilization measures and its effects on - Philippine Institute ...

price stabilization measures and its effects on - Philippine Institute ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

udget subsidy needed to implement the lower domestic <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> but they gain at the expense of theproducers who must pay an implicit tax of the same amount per unit. A major effect of such apolicy is to thus alter income distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> resource allocati<strong>on</strong> patterns. Efficiency losses orwelfare losses arise due to distorti<strong>on</strong>s in the allocati<strong>on</strong> of resources from their most efficient usesin producti<strong>on</strong> or c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>. To compound the problem, subsidies are difficult to administerfor political <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> administrative reas<strong>on</strong>s. The subsidies are channeled to individuals through agovernment bureaucracy which creates <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> own inefficiencies <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> disincentives to exp<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> output(Timmer, 1986). In short, <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> support <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> input subsidy programs are expensive programs forthe government to pursue <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> thereby are not sustainable. Hence, this paper attempts to suggestsome n<strong>on</strong>-<str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>measures</str<strong>on</strong>g> to c<strong>on</strong>trol inflati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> achieve <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> stability.The export sector st<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>s to greatly benefit from a regime of stable <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. One of thefactors affecting the competitiveness of <strong>Philippine</strong> exports has been increasing factor costs orinput costs. Unpredictability in <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s of inputs has resulted in less flexibility <strong>on</strong> the part ofexporters who are unable to efficiently plan ahead. Further eroding the competitiveness of ourexports is the str<strong>on</strong>g competiti<strong>on</strong> from cheap producers like China <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Vietnam.CONCEPT OF INFLATION AND RELATED ISSUESInflati<strong>on</strong> refers to the ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> of c<strong>on</strong>tinuously rising general level of <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s ofgoods <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> services, resulting in a loss of the purchasing power of m<strong>on</strong>ey. The inflati<strong>on</strong> rate is<strong>on</strong>e of the comm<strong>on</strong> indicators derived from the C<strong>on</strong>sumer Price Index (CPI) which is a measureof the average retail <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> of a st<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>ard “basket” of goods <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> services c<strong>on</strong>sumed by a typicalFilipino family. The compositi<strong>on</strong> of such st<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>ard basket is determined by a Family Income <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>Expenditure Survey (FIES) periodically c<strong>on</strong>ducted by the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Statistics Office (NSO). Inbrief, the <strong>Philippine</strong> CPI basket is accounted for by food items (58.5 percent), housing <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>repairs (13.3 percent), clothing (4.4 percent), services (10.9 percent), fuel, light <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> water (5.4percent) <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> miscellaneous items (7.6 percent). Because food accounts for more than half ofthe index, variati<strong>on</strong>s in agricultural output, either due to seas<strong>on</strong>al factors or low agriculturalproductivity have made the inflati<strong>on</strong> rate more volatile. Inefficiencies in the agricultural sectorhave led to a system chain reacti<strong>on</strong> in the ec<strong>on</strong>omy. These inefficiencies have led to higherinflati<strong>on</strong>, dem<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> for higher wages, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sequently, the instituti<strong>on</strong> of food policies.Several studies have raised the questi<strong>on</strong> as to the suitability of the CPI as a measure ofinflati<strong>on</strong> especially for m<strong>on</strong>etary policy. Crawford, et. al. (1997), for example, c<strong>on</strong>sidered twoother <str<strong>on</strong>g>measures</str<strong>on</strong>g> of aggregate <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s: the implicit gross domestic product (GDP) deflator, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> unitlabor costs. There are also issues as to how the underlying or “core” inflati<strong>on</strong> should bemeasured <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the size of the bias in CPI inflati<strong>on</strong>. The core inflati<strong>on</strong> index excludes either foodor energy products or both in order to reduce volatility in inflati<strong>on</strong> figures. If food is removedfrom the commodity basket, more moderate declines or increases in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s of goods <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>services than what the official inflati<strong>on</strong> data shows will be recorded.2


Types of Inflati<strong>on</strong>There are essentially three types of inflati<strong>on</strong>: dem<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> pull, cost push, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> structuralinflati<strong>on</strong>. Dem<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> pull inflati<strong>on</strong> is caused by higher aggregate dem<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> compared to availablesupply or aggregate dem<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> exceeding full employment output. Cost push inflati<strong>on</strong> ischaracterized by the rise in <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s resulting from increases in the cost of producti<strong>on</strong> withoutcorresp<strong>on</strong>ding increases in output. Examples of this would be increases not matched byincreased productivity of labor, hikes in internati<strong>on</strong>al oil <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s, higher cost of capital, increasesin <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s of raw materials, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> hikes in rental rates. Structural inflati<strong>on</strong> occurs when there aredeficiencies in certain c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s in the ec<strong>on</strong>omy such as a backward agricultural sector that isunable to resp<strong>on</strong>d to the people’s increased dem<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> for food, inefficient distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> storagefacilities leading to artificial shortages of goods, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> producti<strong>on</strong> of goods c<strong>on</strong>trolled by somepeople.There are evidences to show that past <strong>Philippine</strong> inflati<strong>on</strong>ary trends have been influencedby a combinati<strong>on</strong> of the three causes, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> these are often times interrelated to <strong>on</strong>e another. Whenseveral types of inflati<strong>on</strong> occur simultaneously, it may be necessary to adopt a set of <str<strong>on</strong>g>measures</str<strong>on</strong>g> toaddress the underlying forces behind the <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> changes. There are trade-offs to reck<strong>on</strong> with suchas the observed tendency of <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> unemployment to move in opposite directi<strong>on</strong>s. Slowingthe rate of inflati<strong>on</strong> may mean an increase in the level of unemployment, lower levels of output,<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> a possible recessi<strong>on</strong> in the ec<strong>on</strong>omy.Cost <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Benef<str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> of Low Inflati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Price StabilityThere have been studies <strong>on</strong> the gains from <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> stability. For example, Feldstein (1997)has shown that inflati<strong>on</strong> exacerbates the tax distorti<strong>on</strong>s that would exist even with <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> stability.The annual deadweight loss of a two percent inflati<strong>on</strong> rate is a large <strong>on</strong>e percent of GDP. Sincethe real gain from shifting to <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> stability grows in perpetuity at the rate of growth of GDP, <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g>present value is a substantial multiple of this annual gain. Discounting the annual gains at therate that investors require for risky equity investments implies a present value equal to more than35 percent of the initial level of GDP. Since the estimated cost of shifting from two percentinflati<strong>on</strong> to <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> stability is about five percent of GDP, the gain substantially outweighs the costof transiti<strong>on</strong> (Feldstein, 1997).Available evidence suggests that the benef<str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> stability are many <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> large whilethe costs of getting there are transitory <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> small by comparis<strong>on</strong>. Moreover, progress towards<str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> stability is easier when wages <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s are flexible <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> when the m<strong>on</strong>etary authority hascredibility (Selody, 1997).Inflati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> GrowthThere is a large <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> growing body of empirical literature <strong>on</strong> the relati<strong>on</strong>ship betweeninflati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> l<strong>on</strong>g-run ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. Despite this effort, robust estimates of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>effects</str<strong>on</strong>g> ofinflati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> growth remain elusive. While most studies showed a negative relati<strong>on</strong>ship, therange of estimates was large, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> many studies found that the relati<strong>on</strong>ship was not statisticallysignificant (Ambler <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Cardia, 1997). Using a general equilibrium model, they showed that3


<str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s of imported inputs. A larger group of structuralists comprising the sec<strong>on</strong>d group, however,views inflati<strong>on</strong> arising from the unbalanced growth of different sectors <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> producti<strong>on</strong>bottlenecks.The first type of producti<strong>on</strong> bottleneck stems from a slow growth of the export sector,usually primary exports, which leads to export earnings being inadequate to support the importrequirements of industries. Since export earnings fall short of the import needs, this leads to aslow growth of aggregate supply which means a persistent excess dem<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> exerting ac<strong>on</strong>tinuous upward pressure <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. This phenomen<strong>on</strong> also c<strong>on</strong>tributes to the unevenrelati<strong>on</strong>ship between exports <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s; an increase in export earnings may have an inflati<strong>on</strong>aryeffect by increasing aggregate dem<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> but a fall in export earnings will exert or have no effect atall <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s due to the structuralist argument <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> because <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s are sticky downwards.A c<strong>on</strong>stant shortage of food is the sec<strong>on</strong>d major bottleneck. A persistent shortage of fooddue to the backwardness of the sector would provide an upward push <strong>on</strong> the general <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> level.Meanwhile, the downward rigidity of <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in the n<strong>on</strong>-food sector which may be due to them<strong>on</strong>opolistic or oligopolistic structure of the sector or str<strong>on</strong>g trade uni<strong>on</strong>s would also cause thegeneral level of <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s to rise.Other major bottlenecks may be traced to structural features of the ec<strong>on</strong>omy such aslagged development of transportati<strong>on</strong>, communicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> other infrastructure, graft, corrupti<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> other types of bureaucratic delays as well as insufficient capital formati<strong>on</strong>. These bottlenecksdiminish the competitiveness of industries. Figure 1 shows the structuralist view of <strong>Philippine</strong>inflati<strong>on</strong>.Several studies have dealt with the welfare <str<strong>on</strong>g>effects</str<strong>on</strong>g> of inflati<strong>on</strong> as well as the benef<str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> of<str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> stability. When the present value of the benef<str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> of low inflati<strong>on</strong> is compared with thepresent value of the cost of achieving (<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> maintaining) low inflati<strong>on</strong>, the c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> arrived at isthat the benef<str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> of reducing inflati<strong>on</strong>, which stem from both the reduced cost of holding m<strong>on</strong>eybalances <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the eliminati<strong>on</strong> of distorti<strong>on</strong>s in the tax system, outweigh the costs.The immediate impact of inflati<strong>on</strong> is a decline in the purchasing power or in the amountof goods <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> services any given amount of m<strong>on</strong>ey can buy. Thus, households with a fixedincome can <strong>on</strong>ly buy a smaller amount of goods <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> services. Unfortunately, these usually tendto be low- income households while higher-income households have more flexibility t<strong>on</strong>eutralize inflati<strong>on</strong> by investing in assets that hold their value against inflati<strong>on</strong>.With the declining value of m<strong>on</strong>ey, people would be more inclined to spend than save,anticipating that their m<strong>on</strong>ey can buy even less in the future. Therefore, inflati<strong>on</strong> has adverse<str<strong>on</strong>g>effects</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> savings <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> investment.5


Figure 1. Structuralist View of <strong>Philippine</strong> Inflati<strong>on</strong>Causes of Inflati<strong>on</strong> Policy Measures to C<strong>on</strong>trolInflati<strong>on</strong>Cost-PushAdvocatesUnbalancedStructural Growth<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Producti<strong>on</strong>Bottleneckshigh wageshigh power rateshigh <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s ofimported inputsslow growth of primary exportsc<strong>on</strong>stant shortage of foodother structural features such aslagged development oftransportati<strong>on</strong>/communicati<strong>on</strong>,insufficient capital formati<strong>on</strong>Inflati<strong>on</strong>development of the export sectorliberalize food trade <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> fooddiversificati<strong>on</strong>increase investment in infrastructure,research <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> developmentdevelopment of the financial sector6


Inflati<strong>on</strong> can also erode the profitability of producers <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the external competitiveness ofdomestic products if it leads to higher producti<strong>on</strong> costs such as wage increases, higher interestrate <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> currency depreciati<strong>on</strong>. Price stability is critical for producers <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> exporters alikebecause high <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> volatile <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s of inputs reduce the flexibility of producers to efficiently planahead. Increases in wage rates which are unmatched by increases in labor productivityeffectively result in higher producti<strong>on</strong> costs for the firm. This is especially important for firms orindustries which are labor intensive like the fruit-processing industry. The industry employsmanual labor for sorting, cooking, bottling <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> packing <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> products. The export industries als<strong>on</strong>eed stable <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s for their inputs to be able to resp<strong>on</strong>d quickly to new trends in market dem<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>.Otherwise, when firms are unable to do so, competiti<strong>on</strong> from cheap producers like China <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>Vietnam will capture the market.Most export industries also suffer from weak backward linkages. The garments industry,which used to be the banner export industry of the country, is forced to import more than half of<str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> input requirements leading to high materials costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> l<strong>on</strong>ger turnaround time. This is alsotrue for the electr<strong>on</strong>ics industry which sources a great porti<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> materials from abroad. Theseindustries require stable <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s to maintain their presence in the global market. These industriesalso need to be able to compete in the higher end segment of their market; <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> stability willhelp these industries to do so. A period of stable <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s will give the export industries time tofocus their strategies in improving <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> maintaining their global competitiveness without havingto worry about how much producti<strong>on</strong> costs will be because <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s are rising unpredictably.Empirical Studies <strong>on</strong> the Causes of Price Instability in the <strong>Philippine</strong>sA review of the factors affecting <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> stability in the <strong>Philippine</strong>s will enable policymakers to implement appropriate policies to maintain <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> changes at a manageable level.Lim (1996) showed that cost-push <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> dem<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>-pull factors are important factors in thedeterminati<strong>on</strong> of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> level. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> of imported goods has the highest elasticity, followedby wages <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>ey supply.An earlier study of Bautista (1983) showed that a large part of inflati<strong>on</strong> for the period1965-1982 could be attributed to world <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> increases <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the depreciati<strong>on</strong> of the peso. Hepointed out also that the increase in oil <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s put more upward pressure <strong>on</strong> inflati<strong>on</strong>. However,his study did not find m<strong>on</strong>ey supply <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> wages to significantly affect inflati<strong>on</strong>.Another study of Lim (1985) indicated that the increase in inflati<strong>on</strong> was caused by therise in interest rates which increased the cost of borrowing for working capital. This wassupported by his empirical results that indicated a positive relati<strong>on</strong>ship between interest rates <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>inflati<strong>on</strong>. Meanwhile, Bautista (1991) showed that the forecast error variance of inflati<strong>on</strong> due tochanges in the exchange rate was higher than that of m<strong>on</strong>ey supply growth. However, theempirical result of his study did not show that m<strong>on</strong>ey supply growth fuelled by fiscal defic<str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g>,was unimportant. Important items in producti<strong>on</strong> cost c<strong>on</strong>sist of wages, salaries, power rates, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>energy <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. Structuralists who advocate a cost-push driven inflati<strong>on</strong> have pointed out thatinflati<strong>on</strong>ary pressures are generated by increases in nominal wage rates in excess of laborproductivity. As <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s of food commodity rise, putting pressure <strong>on</strong> wages to increase <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>7


engendering further <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> increases in the other sectors of the ec<strong>on</strong>omy, a vicious cycle willoccur. This upsurge in the cost of living will push wages to increase independently ofproductivity movements.Wage rates in Manila are pegged at $7/day while in Bangkok, labor rates are at$5.75/day. These have greatly affected labor-intensive industries utilizing low-skilled labor likethe fruit-processing, textile, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> local garments industries.Power rates <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> energy <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s tend to influence the <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s of output that causeinflati<strong>on</strong>ary pressures in the ec<strong>on</strong>omy. The <strong>Philippine</strong>s has the highest retail <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> of electricityin the ASEAN regi<strong>on</strong> although <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> electrificati<strong>on</strong> level is comparable with neighbors of similarlevel of development (NEDA, 1998). Electricity rates in the country in 1997 were at$0.1128/kwh while in Singapore, electricity costs were just $0.0865/kwh (Payumo, 1998).Bernardo (1999) asserted that privatizati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> increased competiti<strong>on</strong> particularly at thegenerati<strong>on</strong> end could reduce power costs from the current average cost of the Nati<strong>on</strong>al PowerCorporati<strong>on</strong> of P2.60/kwh to P1.60/kwh, or as much as 38 percent.TRENDS IN INFLATION IN THE PHILIPPINESThe annual inflati<strong>on</strong> rate in the <strong>Philippine</strong>s has almost always been positive over the pastfour decades (Table 1). Not <strong>on</strong>ly has CPI grown m<strong>on</strong>ot<strong>on</strong>ically but <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> growth has been ratherrapid, compared to many developed <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> developing countries. In certain episodes of the postwarec<strong>on</strong>omic history, inflati<strong>on</strong> was double digit. These are much lower, however, than thehyperinflati<strong>on</strong> type suffered by countries like Argentina, Mexico, Russia, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> recently Ind<strong>on</strong>esia.Since 1992, the average annual inflati<strong>on</strong> rate has been kept at a single digit. A rate of 8.9percent was posted in 1992, a marked decelerati<strong>on</strong> from the 18.7 percent in the previous year. In1993, inflati<strong>on</strong> decelerated further to 7.6 percent. Inflati<strong>on</strong> was higher at 9.0 percent in1994, butstill within the 9.5 percent target inflati<strong>on</strong> in the ec<strong>on</strong>omic <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial program supported bythe Internati<strong>on</strong>al M<strong>on</strong>etary Fund (IMF).8


Table 1. Average rates of inflati<strong>on</strong>, selected countries, 1960-1996.Country 1960-69 1970-79 1980-89 1990-90 1960-96ArgentinaAustraliaBangladeshDominican RepublicIndiaInd<strong>on</strong>esiaJapanMalaysiaMyanmarPakistanPeru<strong>Philippine</strong>sSingaporeThail<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>United States22.422.314.491.846.50232.605.550.834.133.3016.674.621.182.562.42127.939.8319.609.207.5416.929.095.5010.8611.7626.8414.645.918.007.10570.508.4111.2620.879.129.632.533.6510.097.27481.1615.052.795.825.55361.273.214.5219.0410.068.621.443.9724.1710.771151.3910.702.525.123.42269.866.2710.5712.528.2167.204.903.5211.558.21369.1611.483.205.474.78Source of Basic Data: World Development Indicators, The World Bank, 1998Based <strong>on</strong> CPI (1987=100)Several cost-push factors tended to raise inflati<strong>on</strong>ary pressures (Tables 2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> 3). Theseincluded temporary agricultural shortages spawned by the series of typho<strong>on</strong>s in December 1993,phased increases in minimum wages in December 1993 <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> April 1994, some speculati<strong>on</strong>s aboutthe temporary fuel <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> increases early in the year <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impending implementati<strong>on</strong> of theexp<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>ed value-added tax (EVAT). A depreciating peso <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the uptrend in interest rates <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> inm<strong>on</strong>ey supply growth also partly pushed <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s upward during the period.Prices during the first half of 1995 were generally stable despite some unanticipatedexternal shocks <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the rising domestic liquidity in the early part of the year. However, this trendwas reversed in the last four m<strong>on</strong>ths of the year as the rice shortage pushed inflati<strong>on</strong> to doubledigitlevels. Supply-side factors such as the dry spell which significantly affected rice <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> cornproducti<strong>on</strong>, the resulting rice shortage which was aggravated by hoarding <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> delayed riceimportati<strong>on</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the foot-<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>-mouth disease in hogs c<strong>on</strong>tributed to the increase in <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. For1995, inflati<strong>on</strong> averaged 8.0 percent compared with the year-ago level of 9.0 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> thewhole year target of 6.5-7.5 percent. For the first quarter of 1996, inflati<strong>on</strong> remained doubledigitat an average of 11.6 percent. The lingering effect of the rice shortage, the implementati<strong>on</strong>of the EVAT, the increase in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s of oil products, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> their combined influence <strong>on</strong> higher<str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> expectati<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>tributed significantly to this relatively high <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> regime.The recent financial crises resulted in a higher inflati<strong>on</strong> rate in 1997 <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1998, but werec<strong>on</strong>tained within the single digit target level. In 1998, inflati<strong>on</strong> rose to 9.7 percent (1994=100)due mainly to weather-related disturbances <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> lagged <str<strong>on</strong>g>effects</str<strong>on</strong>g> of the sharply depreciated peso9


<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> high interest rates. However, the inflati<strong>on</strong> rate was below the government’s target of 9.25-9.75 percent.In the <strong>Philippine</strong> c<strong>on</strong>text at least, inflati<strong>on</strong> is still regarded as a threat to macroec<strong>on</strong>omicstability. After being maintained at a single digit level for the past four years, 1995–1998,inflati<strong>on</strong> reached double digit in the first quarter of 1999. The <strong>Philippine</strong>s remains to be <strong>on</strong>e ofthe high inflati<strong>on</strong> countries in Asia, although the average inflati<strong>on</strong> rate of 8.2 percent from 1995to 1998 was better compared to other Asian countries affected by the financial crisis. Incomparis<strong>on</strong> to other Asian countries, <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> movements in the <strong>Philippine</strong>s used to acceleratefaster. In 1992, the inflati<strong>on</strong> rates of Malaysia, Taiwan, Thail<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Singapore were recordedat 4.7 percent, 4.5 percent, 4.2 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> 2.3 percent, respectively, as compared to the<strong>Philippine</strong>s' 8.9 percent. Nevertheless, the inflati<strong>on</strong> differential has narrowed down as thecountry's inflati<strong>on</strong> has moved more closely to those of said Asian countries.Nominal interest rates for both borrowing <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> lending instruments of banks slightlyincreased from 1992 to 1998. However, the growth in domestic interest rate is decreasing whichcould be the result of the efforts of the government to bring down the bank’s cost of borrowing.In additi<strong>on</strong>, the downward trend of the nominal interest rate could have also been influenced bythe BSP’s policy of reducing the reserve requirements of banks that resulted in the reducti<strong>on</strong> ofthe intermediati<strong>on</strong> cost. Furthermore, the moral suasi<strong>on</strong> adopted by the BSP over banks tooperate in a manner that will c<strong>on</strong>tribute to the attainment of the m<strong>on</strong>etary goal of the governmentbut c<strong>on</strong>sistent with the profit maximizati<strong>on</strong> of the banks also helped in the reducti<strong>on</strong> of theinterest rate.Table 2. C<strong>on</strong>sumer Price Index (CPI), <strong>Philippine</strong>s, 1995-1998ITEMS 1995 1996 1997 1998Food <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Beverages 109.0 120.4 124.5 135.8Clothing 106.2 112.0 119.3 128.6Housing <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Repair 111.1 122.9 135.7 151.4Fuel, Light <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Water 103.1 109.4 119.4 126.4Services 106.4 115.7 129.6 148.1Miscellaneous 102.8 102.7 106.4 115.2All 108.0 117.8 124.8 136.9Source: Selected <strong>Philippine</strong> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Indicator, BSP, April 1999.10


Table 3. C<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to inflati<strong>on</strong> by commodity, <strong>Philippine</strong>s, 1995-1998ITEMS 1995 1996 1997 1998Food <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Beverages 5.00 5.80 1.90 4.85Clothing 0.20 0.20 0.20 0.29Housing <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Repair 1.60 1.60 1.50 1.70Fuel, Light <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Water 0.20 0.30 0.50 0.34Services 0.80 1.10 1.50 1.80Miscellaneous 0.20 0.00 0.30 0.70All 8.00 9.10 5.90 9.70Source: Selected <strong>Philippine</strong> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Indicator, BSP, April 1999.PERFORMANCE OF THE EXPORT SECTORExports c<strong>on</strong>tinued to grow from U.S. $ 20,543 milli<strong>on</strong> in 1996 to U.S. $ 29,496 milli<strong>on</strong> in1998 (Table 4). However the rate of growth of export decreased from 22.81 percent in 1996-97to 16.92 percent in 1997-98. Imports <strong>on</strong> the other h<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>, experienced a downward trend fromU.S. $ 36,355 milli<strong>on</strong> in 1996 to U.S. $ 29,524 milli<strong>on</strong> in 1998. With the positive growth ofexports of 16.92 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> a negative growth of 18.79 percent in imports <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> because of thepeso devaluati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic slowdown, the trade balance deficit declined significantly toabout U.S. $ 28 milli<strong>on</strong> in 1998 (compared to U.S. $ 11.13 billi<strong>on</strong> trade deficit in 1997).Tables 4 <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> 5 show the performance of the export sector. In 1998, the total value of<strong>Philippine</strong> merch<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>ise export amounted to US $ 29.496 milli<strong>on</strong> or about 43 percent of GNP atcurrent <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. Total exports have shown an impressive growth in the last five years. In 1998,total exports grew by about 17 percent, although it declined slightly compared to the 1996-97growth rate of about 23 percent. However, deeper analysis shows that this export success islargely illusory (Table 5).The structure of the export sector is lopsided. It is dominated by <strong>on</strong>ly two manufacturingindustries: the electr<strong>on</strong>ics or semi-c<strong>on</strong>ductor <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the garment industries. In 1998, the electr<strong>on</strong>ics<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> garment industries c<strong>on</strong>tributed about 58 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> 8 percent of the total export receipts,respectively. Thus, the two industries c<strong>on</strong>tributed more that 65 percent of the total export value.This structure has been existing since the 1980’s. It is interesting to note, however, that the twoindustries have very limited c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to the domestic ec<strong>on</strong>omy because substantial amountsof their input requirements are imported. Take the case of the electr<strong>on</strong>ic industry; the countrydoes not have the technology to supply <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> input requirements. It sources from 75 to 90 percent of<str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> materials from abroad. The garment industry, <strong>on</strong> the other h<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>, has to import raw fabric to becompetitive in the world market because of the inefficiency of the local textile industry. Thus,11


Table 4. <strong>Philippine</strong> exports by major commodity, 1990-1998 (In milli<strong>on</strong> U.S. $)Commodity Group 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998Coc<strong>on</strong>ut Products 496 439 633 494 607 974 730 835 831Sugar <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Sugar Products 133 136 110 139 77 74 139 99 100Fru<str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Vegetables 326 393 371 439 429 458 486 459 446Other Agri-Based Products 431 504 432 476 530 575 506 506 465Forest Products 94 73 57 45 26 38 42 45 24Mineral Products 442 388 416 422 510 552 772 764 591Petroleum Products 155 175 150 136 132 171 273 157 129Manufacturers 5995 6633 7525 9031 10917 14224 17106 21488 25866Elec. & Elec. Eqpt./Parts & Telecom 1964 2293 2753 3551 4984 7413 9990 13052 17156Garments 1776 1861 2140 2272 2375 2570 2423 2349 2356Special Transacti<strong>on</strong>s 19 17 37 38 74 108 157 263 311Re-exports 95 82 98 165 181 273 332 512 733TOTAL EXPORTS 8186 8840 9829 11375 13483 17447 20543 25228 29496Source: Foreign Trade Divisi<strong>on</strong>, NSOYear12


Table 5. <strong>Philippine</strong> exports by major commodity, 1990-1998 (In percent change).YearCommodity Group 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998Coc<strong>on</strong>ut Products (11.49) 44.19 (21.96) 22.87 60.46 (25.05) 14.38 (0.48)Sugar <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Sugar Products 2.26 (19.12) 17.27 (40.31) (3.90) 87.84 (28.78) 1.01Fruit <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Vegetables 20.55 (5.60) 18.33 (2.28) 6.76 6.11 (5.56) (2.83)Other Agri-Based Products 16.94 (14.29) 10.19 11.34 8.49 (12.00) 0.00 (8.10)Forest Products (22.34) (21.92) (21.05) (42.22) 46.15 10.53 7.14 (46.67)Mineral Products (12.22) 7.22 1.44 20.85 8.24 39.86 (1.04) (22.64)Petroleum Products 12.90 (14.29) (9.33) (2.94) 29.55 59.65 (5.86) (49.81)Manufactures 10.64 13.45 20.01 20.88 30.29 20.26 25.62 20.37Elec. & Elec. Eqpt/Parts & Telecom 16.75 20.06 28.99 40.35 48.74 34.76 30.65 31.44Garments 4.79 14.99 6.17 4.53 8.21 (5.72) (3.05) 0.30Special Transacti<strong>on</strong>s (10.53) 117.65 2.70 94.74 45.95 45.37 67.52 18.25Re-exports (13.68) 19.51 68.37 9.70 50.83 21.61 54.22 43.16TOTAL EXPORTS 7.99 11.19 15.73 18.53 29.40 17.75 22.81 16.9213


while the two industries c<strong>on</strong>tributed substantially to the total export receipts, they are also themajor users of such receipts through imports of their raw material requirements. In net terms,their c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to the total export value has been minimal.Although total exports grew by about 17 percent in 1997-98, the traditi<strong>on</strong>al exportproducts (e.g., coc<strong>on</strong>ut, sugar, fru<str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> vegetable, etc.), have generally been in a dismal stagewith <strong>on</strong>ly sugar <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> sugar products showing a positive growth rate of 1.01 percent in 1997-98(Table 5).In the last two years, machinery <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> transport equipment replaced the garment industry asthe sec<strong>on</strong>d largest c<strong>on</strong>tributor to the total export value. In 1998, it c<strong>on</strong>tributed 11 percent of thetotal export receipts. The electr<strong>on</strong>ics industry, however, c<strong>on</strong>tinues to c<strong>on</strong>tribute substantially tothe growth of the export sector. In fact, it c<strong>on</strong>tributed about 58 percent of the total export valuein 1998.Although the <strong>Philippine</strong>s showed the highest export growth in 1998 compared to otherAsian countries, it is <strong>on</strong>e of the few (including India <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Sri-Lanka) countries still experiencing anegative balance of trade. This c<strong>on</strong>tinuous negative balance of trade despite a significant increasein export is due to the import dependence of the export sector for their inputs.POLICY REFORMS TO STABILIZE PRICES AND SUSTAINECONOMIC GROWTHUnder a free market system, <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s of basic commodities are determined by dem<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>supply c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s. Domestic supply, is, in turn, determined by domestic producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>foreign trade. Measures that promote, therefore, domestic producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> improve access toforeign supplies of commodities can help stabilize <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. This implies that a more liberalizedtrade regime is beneficial towards <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> stability.The government, through <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> various agencies, is pursuing producti<strong>on</strong>-related programs<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> has instituted policies to enhance productivity, efficiency, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> competitiveness. Theseinclude producti<strong>on</strong> programs, training, provisi<strong>on</strong> of basic infrastructure like irrigati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> farmto-market roads, shipping ports, storage <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> post harvest facilities, credit, etc. There are alsol<strong>on</strong>g- term programs such as increased agricultural research expenditures. For agriculture, theproductivity <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> efficiency enhancing <str<strong>on</strong>g>measures</str<strong>on</strong>g> are c<strong>on</strong>tained in the Agricultural <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> FisheriesModernizati<strong>on</strong> Act (AFMA).Measures to improve competitiveness such as improved productivity <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> efficiency ofthe country's products in the world market are also beneficial in terms of <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> stability. Therecent commitment of the country to the World Trade Organizati<strong>on</strong> (WTO) has, thereforeimproved the country's chances of achieving <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> stability through trade liberalizati<strong>on</strong>particularly of basic commodities. When the country is in short supply of a certain commodity, amore liberalized trade regime would prevent a large hike in domestic <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s.14


It appears then that while <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>stabilizati<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> is the prime resp<strong>on</strong>sibility of the BSPthrough the prudent use of m<strong>on</strong>etary policies, fiscal policy also plays an important role, not <strong>on</strong>lyin terms of appropriate tax <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> expenditure policies but also specifically in fostering a morec<strong>on</strong>ducive ec<strong>on</strong>omic envir<strong>on</strong>ment within which producers in agriculture <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>-agriculture areoperating. The possible <str<strong>on</strong>g>measures</str<strong>on</strong>g> which can help combat inflati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> promote <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> stabilitywithin the country are as follows:Producti<strong>on</strong>-related MeasuresFor the years 1993-1998, the agriculture sector exhibited relatively low levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> growthof productivity. Average annual growth rates in yield for palay <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> corn were <strong>on</strong>ly 0.6 percent<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> 2.8 percent respectively. Abaca, coc<strong>on</strong>ut, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> sugarcane had negative rates; 5.6 percent, 0.2percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> 5.3 percent, respectively, pulling the agricultural sub-sector's productivity to anegative rate of 7.2 percent. (Table 6). The limited <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> inefficient provisi<strong>on</strong> of support serviceswas a significant factor to low level <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> growth of agricultural productivity in the country.Irrigated l<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>ly slightly increased. Inadequate postharvest facilities were manifested insignificant postharvest losses <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor infrastructure impeded the flow of agriculturalcommodities (Medium-Term Development Plan 1999 - 2004, NEDA).Table 6. Average growth in yield (MT/ha.) for agricultural crops, <strong>Philippine</strong>s, 1993-1997Sub-sectorAverage Annual Growth1993-1997AGRICULTURAL CROPS (7.2)MAJOR CROPSPalayCornCoc<strong>on</strong>utSugarcaneBananaPineappleCoffeeMangoTobaccoAbacaOther Crops(12.2)0.62.8(0.2)(5.3)1.917.6(0.8)6.00.4(5.6)7.0Source: Report <strong>on</strong> the Performance of Agriculture, Bureau of Agricultural Statistics.15


Some ec<strong>on</strong>omists predict that the country will bounce back from the ec<strong>on</strong>omic crisis bythe end of 1999. However, the rate of ec<strong>on</strong>omic recovery will depend <strong>on</strong> the government policyadjustments in order to improve the balance of payments, lower inflati<strong>on</strong> rate, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> sustainec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. Favorable weather c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>, which is an exogenous factor <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> theimprovement in peace <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> order c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> are also c<strong>on</strong>sidered important to promote stability inoutput. While the immediate c<strong>on</strong>cern of the government is to address the ec<strong>on</strong>omic vulnerabilityof the country brought about by the financial crisis, l<strong>on</strong>g-term soluti<strong>on</strong>s to lower inflati<strong>on</strong> rate<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> sustain ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth should be given top priority. Some of the producti<strong>on</strong>-related<str<strong>on</strong>g>measures</str<strong>on</strong>g> are as follows:1. Increase investments in infrastructure <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> research <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> development. Studies in therole of infrastructure in Mexican Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Reform (Feltenstein <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ha, 1995) haveshown that improvements in infrastructure (e.g., electricity <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> communicati<strong>on</strong>) helpincrease output <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> stabilize <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. Improvement in road <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> infrastructure facilities isa pre-requisite to the social <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic development of the country. Improvements ininfrastructure would enable producers to reduce the unacceptable high cost of marketing<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> in some cases, even open up access to market for remote producers/farmers.Furthermore, it would minimize the delays in the delivery of goods <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> services <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>boost producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> thereby increase the income of small producers without necessarilyincreasing the <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s of their products.To help facilitate the improvement of infrastructure, the Department of Trade <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>Industry (DTI), the Department of Agriculture (DA), <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Local Government Un<str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g>(LGUs) can assist the Department of Public Works <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Highways (DPWH) in settingpriorities for infrastructure development in areas where lack of transport <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> otherproducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> post-producti<strong>on</strong> facilities are major c<strong>on</strong>straints in increasing food supply.2. Increase irrigati<strong>on</strong> investment. Investment in irrigati<strong>on</strong> includes new irrigati<strong>on</strong>development <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> rehabilitati<strong>on</strong> of existing irrigati<strong>on</strong> systems. New irrigati<strong>on</strong>development will result in the c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> of rainfed areas to irrigated l<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> marginalto productive l<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. With the increase in area planted <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> cropping intensity due toavailability of water, agricultural producti<strong>on</strong> is expected to increase. The impact of thedrought brought about by the “El Niño phenomen<strong>on</strong>” could have been minimized if asuitable irrigati<strong>on</strong> system had been developed. More l<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>s devoted to agriculturalproducti<strong>on</strong> will increase food supply <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> stabilize <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s.3. Provide proper incentives to the financial sector to increase their credit exposure inthe agricultural sector. The anticipated favorable effect of the devaluati<strong>on</strong> of the peso<strong>on</strong> exports was not felt because of the tightening of credit due to higher interest rate. Withhigh cost of credit, small exporters could not exp<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> their capacity <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> could not affordto increase their imported inputs. The availability of credit to small producers is essentialfor sustained ec<strong>on</strong>omic development through increased productivity. The availability oflow cost credit to small producers will reduce the cost of producti<strong>on</strong> thus easing thepressure to increase the <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s of their commodities.16


The expected increase in productivity will depend <strong>on</strong> the following c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s: (1)the level of credit availed by the producers is sufficient to purchase the optimal level ofinputs; (2) the loan is used for the intended purpose; <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> (3) the added return in the useof credit is sufficient to pay the added cost of credit4. Increase the role of informal lenders in the provisi<strong>on</strong> of credit. The governmentshould also adopt <str<strong>on</strong>g>measures</str<strong>on</strong>g> to encourage informal lenders to c<strong>on</strong>tinue offering loans butat reas<strong>on</strong>able rates to small producers/farmers. This can be d<strong>on</strong>e also by supporting theinformal credit lenders by providing proper incentives. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the governmentshould help establish cooperatives <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> associati<strong>on</strong>s am<strong>on</strong>g small producers <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> build upfunds through savings <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> government bank rediscounting. With more credit available tosmall <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> medium producers, supply of commodities will be increased which will resultto stable <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s.5. Diversify food producti<strong>on</strong>. Since the country is always a host to str<strong>on</strong>g typho<strong>on</strong>swhich destroy agricultural crops, it is important to diversify producti<strong>on</strong> of agriculturalcrops other than the traditi<strong>on</strong>al crops that are vulnerable to weather-related disturbances,such as root crops. It is also important to develop such other areas that are less affectedby typho<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> other weather disturbances, such as Mindanao. However, this wouldrequire investments in infrastructure investment as well as resolving the peace <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> orderproblem. This program will help increase the supply of food commodities <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> stabilize<str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s.6. Develop the post-harvest sector. The government should support the development ofthe post-harvest sector in order to reduce losses <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> improve the quality of agriculturalcommodities. With improved post-harvest facilities, producers can avail of the incentivesof adopting post-producti<strong>on</strong> practices <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> technology, thus increasing their incomewithout increasing the <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s of goods <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> services. In additi<strong>on</strong>, reducing losses throughimproved post-harvest facilities <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> technologies would clearly increase food availability<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> stabilize <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in the country. The government should require the activeparticipati<strong>on</strong> of different agencies involved in post-harvest development. A lead agencyshould be assigned to coordinate the efforts of different agencies/instituti<strong>on</strong>s to facilitatethe development of the post-harvest sector.7. Liberalize trade in food. The government should c<strong>on</strong>tinue to liberalize the trade in foodcommodities. If we cannot source low-cost supplies of food domestically, then we mustbe prepared to procure low-cost food from the world market. However, the governmentin liberalizing the importati<strong>on</strong> of food items should allow the private sector to participateactively in the importati<strong>on</strong> of agricultural commodities (e.g., grains <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> sugar) duringtimes of shortage <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> export during the surplus period. Opening the internati<strong>on</strong>al marketto the private sector would create incentives for quality improvement <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> employmentopportunities in the country. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the government should help producers of foodto be self-reliant. With sufficient supply of commodities, <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s will be stabilized.17


8. Provide a more effective <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> efficient market informati<strong>on</strong> system (MIS). The MISmust be strengthened to improve marketing efficiency through effective disseminati<strong>on</strong> ofrelevant informati<strong>on</strong> pertaining to producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> marketing. It is envisi<strong>on</strong>ed thatstrengthening the MIS will create a more competitive envir<strong>on</strong>ment am<strong>on</strong>g interestedparties – producers, traders <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sumers- thus improving their ec<strong>on</strong>omic welfare.Effective <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> efficient market informati<strong>on</strong> will decrease the cost of marketing, thuseasing the pressure to increase <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. Furthermore, such informati<strong>on</strong> system would bevery useful for facilitating the intra- <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> inter-regi<strong>on</strong>al trading of commodities in thecountry which would help stabilize <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s.An example of this is the Electr<strong>on</strong>ic System of Trading Agricultural Products program ofthe Nati<strong>on</strong>al Food Authority (NFA) to help facilitate the transacti<strong>on</strong> of corn buyers <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>producers by reducing transacti<strong>on</strong> cost. Corn buyers normally located in Metro Manila<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Cebu can transact business with local corn producers located in Mindanao <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>Northern Luz<strong>on</strong> without spending hundreds of pesos. This program can also be adoptedto other agricultural commodities <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> sectors of the ec<strong>on</strong>omy.Fiscal <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> M<strong>on</strong>etary ReformsMacroec<strong>on</strong>omic management has improved a lot in the <strong>Philippine</strong>s since the Marcosyears. The BSP was made an independent instituti<strong>on</strong>. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, the government had privatized alot of m<strong>on</strong>ey-losing state enterprises, which had drained government finances. However, thesepolicies are not enough to cushi<strong>on</strong> the impact of ec<strong>on</strong>omic crisis. More reforms in m<strong>on</strong>etary,fiscal, exchange rate, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> trade policies should be adopted.1. <strong>Institute</strong> further reforms in financial markets. Measures to boost domestic savingsshould be adopted by the government. In additi<strong>on</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>measures</str<strong>on</strong>g> to attract foreign investorsshould also be implemented. Attracting foreign investors can be achieved by improvingthe stock market operati<strong>on</strong>s through transparency <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> efficiency in <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> operati<strong>on</strong>s. Smallinvestors should likewise be protected to ensure the c<strong>on</strong>tinuity of their participati<strong>on</strong> in thecapital market.The government should try to tap other financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s (e.g., insurance <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>pensi<strong>on</strong> companies) to boost domestic savings <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> help cater to the l<strong>on</strong>g-term investmentrequirement of the country. A neutral <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> unbiased tax system will also encourage otherfinancial instituti<strong>on</strong>s to augment domestic savings. The policy of government ofencouraging mergers am<strong>on</strong>g financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s is a big help in attaining stability in thefinancial system.2. Develop the export sector. The export sector plays an important role in attainingpositive growth in the current account. The performance of the export sector during thefinancial crisis indicates that the development of the export industry as a source of growthin the current account is more sustainable in the l<strong>on</strong>g-run than relying <strong>on</strong> the remittancesof overseas workers.18


With the devaluati<strong>on</strong> of the peso, holding other factors c<strong>on</strong>stant, this should make<strong>Philippine</strong> exports competitive in the world market. However, during the financial crisis,exporters were not able to take advantage of the opportunities due to the lack of capital<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> other markets that were not affected by the financial crisis. The government shouldhelp develop other markets for <strong>Philippine</strong> exports to minimize the impact of ec<strong>on</strong>omicdisturbances. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the government should assist the export sector in improvingthe skill <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> capabilities of their workers to be efficient in the producti<strong>on</strong> of their output.Likewise, the government should help promote the country's export products in othercountries that are not importing <strong>Philippine</strong> products.3. Broaden the tax base <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> improve efficiency in tax collecti<strong>on</strong>. The budget deficitexperienced by the country for so many years was partly attributed to low tax collecti<strong>on</strong>.Government budget defic<str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> if not corrected, so<strong>on</strong>er or later, have to be financed throughm<strong>on</strong>ey creati<strong>on</strong>, which is inflati<strong>on</strong>ary. With the broadening of the tax base <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> efficienttax collecti<strong>on</strong>, the fiscal deficit could be minimized thus easing the pressure <strong>on</strong> interest<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> exchange rates which will help stabilize <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s.4. <strong>Institute</strong> BSP M<strong>on</strong>etary Measures. The BSP has at <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> disposal a number of m<strong>on</strong>etarypolicy <str<strong>on</strong>g>measures</str<strong>on</strong>g> that can eventually influence the movement of <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> levels. Theseinclude regulati<strong>on</strong> of m<strong>on</strong>ey supply, prime interest rates, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> reserve requirement rates.While these are usually used to influence credit c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, the investment climate, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>eventually output <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> employment, these variables can also be used to influence inflati<strong>on</strong>rates. The BSP has kept <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> h<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>s off the dealing floor, allowing the peso to fluctuate <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>seek <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> market rate. While a str<strong>on</strong>g peso can be used to dampen inflati<strong>on</strong>ary pressures,this policy is <strong>on</strong>ly correct to an extent in the short term. Furthermore, the cause ofinflati<strong>on</strong> should be determined. The current inflati<strong>on</strong> is not a m<strong>on</strong>etary phenomen<strong>on</strong> buta cost-push <strong>on</strong>e combined with <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> “El Niño” supply shock or a structural defect. Inadditi<strong>on</strong>, the BSP should be more active in m<strong>on</strong>itoring <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> supervising the financialsystem to prevent defaults in the banking system (e.g., Orient Bank, M<strong>on</strong>te de Piedad,etc.).Issues <strong>on</strong> the Adopti<strong>on</strong> of Inflati<strong>on</strong> Targeting In Developing CountriesInflati<strong>on</strong> targeting is a framework that be used to c<strong>on</strong>duct m<strong>on</strong>etary policy in order tomaintain a low <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> stable rate of inflati<strong>on</strong>. Its adopti<strong>on</strong> would indicate the str<strong>on</strong>gest possiblecommitment by the m<strong>on</strong>etary authorities to deal with the danger of inflati<strong>on</strong>.In an internet article entitled "The Eternal Triangle", Krugman (1999) argued thatcountries face a dilemna in choosing <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>etary regime. The three main goals of adjustment,c<strong>on</strong>fidence <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> liquidity c<strong>on</strong>flict with <strong>on</strong>e another; choosing <strong>on</strong>e implies dropping the otherobjective. Following Krugman's definiti<strong>on</strong> of the three objectives, it looks like the <strong>Philippine</strong>government is trying to strike a balance between the above-menti<strong>on</strong>ed goals. It is allowing thepeso to float, while keeping interest rates low <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> inflati<strong>on</strong> at manageable rates. In effect, theadministrati<strong>on</strong> is putting a premium <strong>on</strong> adjustment <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> liquidity, but at the same timemaintaining a relatively stable exchange rate by allowing the currency to float within a b<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>.19


The country has recently presented to the Internati<strong>on</strong>al M<strong>on</strong>etary Fund a new ec<strong>on</strong>omicprogram with higher growth rates <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> lower inflati<strong>on</strong>. The Estrada administrati<strong>on</strong> is expectinginflati<strong>on</strong> to go down to 7- 8 percent this year. Next year, inflati<strong>on</strong> is projected to go down to 6.5percent. The rise in c<strong>on</strong>sumer <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s would be slower this year <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> next year, with sufficientfood supply, a stable peso <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> a modest current account surplus. The government’s thrust ofeasing interest rate has likewise set the phase for a more positive business envir<strong>on</strong>ment.Unlike other countries, such as Canada <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> New Zeal<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>, the <strong>Philippine</strong>s, has notadopted an explicit inflati<strong>on</strong> target whereby m<strong>on</strong>etary <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal policies are adjusted in resp<strong>on</strong>seto an external shock in order to maintain a specific inflati<strong>on</strong> rate. It appears, however, that thetarget rate of inflati<strong>on</strong> is currently somewhere in the neighborhood of 9 percent.With an inflati<strong>on</strong> target, the resp<strong>on</strong>se of the BSP to a shock that pushes inflati<strong>on</strong> above <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g>target would be to take acti<strong>on</strong> to return the inflati<strong>on</strong> rate to <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> target. In this scenario, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>level would rise as a result of the initial shock, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> then the rate of increase in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> levelwould be reduced until it would again equal the target rate of inflati<strong>on</strong>. Thus, the initial increasein the <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> level would not be reversed, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>, there would be a permanent rise in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> level.However, there are several prerequisites that have to be met in recommending theadopti<strong>on</strong> of core-inflati<strong>on</strong> targeting. For inflati<strong>on</strong> targeting to work, the BSP has to haveoperati<strong>on</strong>al aut<strong>on</strong>omy for m<strong>on</strong>etary policy, a mechanism whereby the BSP is held accountablefor maintaining inflati<strong>on</strong> within the target range, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> a strategy for the transparentcommunicati<strong>on</strong> of m<strong>on</strong>etary policy objectives <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> acti<strong>on</strong>s to both financial markets <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> thegeneral public. By raising the profile of inflati<strong>on</strong>, it will focus the attenti<strong>on</strong> of m<strong>on</strong>etary policymakers <strong>on</strong> the difficult decisi<strong>on</strong>s to be made. For political establishment, the explicit character<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> transparency of the m<strong>on</strong>etary policy arrangement will be helpful in focusing the debate <strong>on</strong>the l<strong>on</strong>ger-term objectives of m<strong>on</strong>etary policy. For the financial markets <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the public at large,the new framework is a key element in establishing expectati<strong>on</strong>s of low inflati<strong>on</strong>. A clear target,together with the transparency <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> frequency of the central bank’s public reports <strong>on</strong> m<strong>on</strong>etarypolicy will allow financial markets to better anticipate the emerging stance of m<strong>on</strong>etary policy<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> thus, reduce surprises.These same prerequisites are menti<strong>on</strong>ed in an internet article <strong>on</strong> inflati<strong>on</strong> targetingwritten by Mass<strong>on</strong>, et. al. (1998). These include the following: (1) the central m<strong>on</strong>etaryauthority must have degree of independence <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> not show any symptom of financial dominance;<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> (2) authorities should refrain from targeting nominal variables, such as the nominalexchange rate since a country which chooses a fixed exchange rate effectively subordinates <str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g>m<strong>on</strong>etary policy to the exchange rate objective. In additi<strong>on</strong> to the above prerequisites, am<strong>on</strong>etary policy framework with essential features needs to be in place. Am<strong>on</strong>g the sevencountries that have so far practiced inflati<strong>on</strong> targeting, a number of features are similar. All theseven countries introduced inflati<strong>on</strong> targeting when the inflati<strong>on</strong> rate was already low. Inadditi<strong>on</strong>, inflati<strong>on</strong> targeting is associated with a high degree of exchange rate flexibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> allinflati<strong>on</strong> targets were forward-looking.20


Before advocating the adopti<strong>on</strong> of core-inflati<strong>on</strong> targeting in the country, the followingquesti<strong>on</strong>s should, therefore, be posed: Does the <strong>Philippine</strong>s meet the above criteria? Is the BSPcapable of c<strong>on</strong>ducting an independent m<strong>on</strong>etary policy? Will inflati<strong>on</strong> rates c<strong>on</strong>tinue to remain ata single digit level? In relati<strong>on</strong> to the degree of Central Bank independence in the developingcountries, Mass<strong>on</strong>, et. al. found out that fiscal dominance <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor financial infrastructure d<strong>on</strong>ot bode well for an independent m<strong>on</strong>etary policy in developing countries. Apart from thesefindings, Mass<strong>on</strong>, et. al. also raised the following additi<strong>on</strong>al issues against the adopti<strong>on</strong> of coreinflati<strong>on</strong>targeting by developing countries:"1. In most developing countries, there is no c<strong>on</strong>sensus about the optimum inflati<strong>on</strong> rate,which is <strong>on</strong>e of the bases for setting the medium-term inflati<strong>on</strong> target. C<strong>on</strong>sequently,any choice of such a target for developing countries might be seen as arbitrary;2. There is also no agreement <strong>on</strong> the speed with which the medium-term inflati<strong>on</strong> targetwould be attained in these ec<strong>on</strong>omies. Some observers have argued that <strong>on</strong>ce adeveloping country has brought down inflati<strong>on</strong> to within the low-to-moderate range,it should adopt a cautious approach to disinflati<strong>on</strong>;3. The choice of a <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> index <strong>on</strong> which to base the inflati<strong>on</strong> target is also likely to bemore problematic in developing countries than in industrial ec<strong>on</strong>omies, since theformer tend to be subject to more numerous <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> variable supply shocks that affect the<str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> index <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> inflati<strong>on</strong>; <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>4. In many developing countries, administered or c<strong>on</strong>trolled <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s are an importantcomp<strong>on</strong>ent of aggregate <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> indices <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> thus, of the short run behavior of inflati<strong>on</strong>.In such cases, a proper inflati<strong>on</strong> forecast would need to take account of the timing <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>extent of changes in those <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. This would require a higher degree of coordinati<strong>on</strong>between m<strong>on</strong>etary <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal authorities than in situati<strong>on</strong>s like those in industrialcountries where most markets are market determined."Based <strong>on</strong> the foregoing discussi<strong>on</strong>s, it is apparent that the prec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for adoptingcore-inflati<strong>on</strong> targeting are not yet present in most developing countries like the <strong>Philippine</strong>s.The issue <strong>on</strong> the degree of independence of the central m<strong>on</strong>etary authority <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the lack ofagreement <strong>on</strong> the optimum inflati<strong>on</strong> rate, the choice of a <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> index, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the speed with whichthe inflati<strong>on</strong> target should be attained complicate the approach of inflati<strong>on</strong> targeting in thecountry.CONCLUDING REMARKSThe <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>stabilizati<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>measures</str<strong>on</strong>g> enumerated above which take the form of producti<strong>on</strong>relatedas well as fiscal <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>etary policies will enable the <strong>Philippine</strong> export sector to weatherfuture crises <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> improve their global competitiveness. Solving the structural bottlenecks inproducti<strong>on</strong> with reforms in the credit market <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> infrastructure will reduce <str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g> movements.Furthermore, reducing the costs of doing business in the country by fostering a climate of stable<str<strong>on</strong>g>price</str<strong>on</strong>g>s will improve the marketability <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> attractiveness of <strong>Philippine</strong>-made products. While thisis not the panacea for the multitude of problems that c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>t the export sector, these <str<strong>on</strong>g>measures</str<strong>on</strong>g>will significantly promote the growth of the industry.21


REFERENCESAmbler, Steve <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Cardia, Emanuela. 1997. “Testing the Link Between Inflati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Growth.”Paper Presented in the C<strong>on</strong>ference <strong>on</strong> “Price Stability, Inflati<strong>on</strong> Targets, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> M<strong>on</strong>etaryPolicy”, Bank of Canada.Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas , 1998.Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas, 1999.1999.Sixth Annual Report.Selected Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Indicators of the <strong>Philippine</strong>s, AprilBautista, C. C. 1991. “Sources <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Variability of Inflati<strong>on</strong> in an Open Ec<strong>on</strong>omy”. University ofthe <strong>Philippine</strong>s School of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper 9115.Bautista, R. M. 1983. “Determinants of Inflati<strong>on</strong> in the <strong>Philippine</strong>s.” University of the<strong>Philippine</strong>s School of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper 8309.Bernardo, Romeo O. 1999. “Jumpstarting Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Recovery.” <strong>Philippine</strong> Daily Inquirer,August 16, 1999, p. 8.Crawford, Allan, Jean-Francois Filli<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Therese Lafleche, 1997. “Is the CPI a SuitableMeasure for Defining Price Stability?” Paper Presented in the C<strong>on</strong>ference <strong>on</strong> “PriceStability, Inflati<strong>on</strong> Targets, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> M<strong>on</strong>etary Policy”, Bank of Canada, May 1997.Danziger, L. 1988. “Cost of Price Adjustment <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Welfare Ec<strong>on</strong>omics of Inflati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>Disinflati<strong>on</strong>,” American Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 78 (4).Duspasquier, Chantal <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Nicholas Ricketts. 1997. “N<strong>on</strong>-Linearities in the Output Inflati<strong>on</strong>Relati<strong>on</strong>ship.” Paper Presented in the C<strong>on</strong>ference <strong>on</strong> “Price Stability, Inflati<strong>on</strong> Targets,<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> M<strong>on</strong>etary Policy”, Bank of Canada, May 1997.Feldstein, Martin. 1997. Reducing Inflati<strong>on</strong>: Motivati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Strategy. In: C. Romer <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> D.Romer, eds., Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Feltenstien, Andrew <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Jiming Ha. 1995. “The Role of Infrastructure in Mexican Ec<strong>on</strong>omicReform.” The World Bank Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review, Volume 9 (2), May 1995.Krugman, Paul, 1999. "The Eternal Triangle". An Internet Article.Lim, J. Y. 1985. “The New Structuralist Critique of the M<strong>on</strong>etarist Theory of Inflati<strong>on</strong>: TheCase of the <strong>Philippine</strong>s”. University of the <strong>Philippine</strong>s School of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics Discussi<strong>on</strong>Paper 8506.Lim, J. Y. 1996. “On the Questi<strong>on</strong> of a Trade-off Between Sustainable Growth <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> PriceStability.” Manuscript.22


Mass<strong>on</strong>, Paul R., Miguel A. Savastano <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Sunil Sharma, 1998. "Can Inflati<strong>on</strong> Targeting Be AFramework for M<strong>on</strong>etary Policy in Developing Countries?" Finance <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Development,March 1998.NEDA, 1999. "Medium-Term Development Plan, 1999 -2004". <strong>Philippine</strong>s.NEDA, 1998. “The <strong>Philippine</strong> Nati<strong>on</strong>al Development Plan, 1998”. <strong>Philippine</strong>s.Payumo, Anita S. 1998. “RP Bets Hobble Toward Finish Line in Global Race.” <strong>Philippine</strong>Daily Inquirer, December 21, 1998, p. 8.Rausser, Gord<strong>on</strong> C. , E. Lichtenberg <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> R. Lattimore, 1982. Developments in Theory <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>Empirical Applicati<strong>on</strong>s of Endogenous Governmental Behavior”. New Directi<strong>on</strong>s inEc<strong>on</strong>ometric Modelling <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Forecasting in U.S. Agriculture, North Holl<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>.Selody, Jack. 1979. The Goal of Price Stability: A Review of the Issue. Technical Report No.54. Bank of Canada.Timmer, C. Peter. Getting Prices Right - The Scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lim<str<strong>on</strong>g>its</str<strong>on</strong>g> of Agricultural Price Policy.Cornell University Press. C. 1986.Yap, Josef T. 1996. “Inflati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Growth in the <strong>Philippine</strong>s”. Paper Presented forthe Joint study <strong>on</strong> “The Fundamental Problem of Rec<strong>on</strong>ciling Policies for Ec<strong>on</strong>omicGrowth <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> Development with Policies for Moderating Inflati<strong>on</strong>”, New Delhi, India, July25-26, 1996.23

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!