05.12.2012 Views

Untitled

Untitled

Untitled

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

also increased it with respect to Radica (see Table 5); In terms of net investment in R&D, although<br />

in the year 2006 Mattel reduced its net investment (as percentage of assets); however, in the quarter<br />

where the negotiation …nished, Mattel increased its expenditures in R&D (see Table 4). Although<br />

it is hard to justify this causality using aggregate data on Mattel’s R&D, it is “possible”that, like<br />

in Gans and Stern model, this increment in R&D expending is a signal that Mattel is sending to<br />

Radica about the seriousness of its strategic plan of obtaining know-how to enter in the electronic<br />

segment of the toy industry. The development of electronic games by Mattel such as AcceleRacer,<br />

Pixel Chix, and Vidster in 2005 follow this line of reasoning, which tend to decrease the expected<br />

value of :<br />

4.4 Equilibrium<br />

Gans and Stern (2000) show that equilibrium exists in their formal game; that is, there is a<br />

where the cost and bene…ts of each …rm “balance”. In that speci…c case the agreement is reached<br />

in the …rst round of negotiation and both …rms maximize, within its own set of restrictions, their<br />

total value. What happened in the Mattel-Radica case? In mid-October both management teams<br />

announced that they had reached an agreement where Mattel bought Radica for $230 million<br />

dollars. In terms of Gans and Stern model, they reached a Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium<br />

where = 230; 000; 000:<br />

4.4.1 Example<br />

In order to get some intuition of this equilibrium output consider a much simpler version of the<br />

Mattel-Radica Acquisition game.<br />

Insert Table 6 around here<br />

17

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!