08.08.2015 Views

Economic Report of the President

Economic Report of the President 1967 - The American Presidency ...

Economic Report of the President 1967 - The American Presidency ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Economic</strong> <strong>Report</strong><strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong>Transmitted to <strong>the</strong> CongressJanuary 1967TOGETHER WITHTHE ANNUAL REPORTOF THECOUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERSUNITED STATES GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICEWASHINGTON : 1967For sale by <strong>the</strong> Superintendent <strong>of</strong> Documents, U.S. Government Printing OfficeWashington, D.C. 20402 - Price $1.25


CONTENTSECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENTPageRECENT ECONOMIC GAINS 3OUR ECONOMIC PROBLEMS 4Some Leading Problems 5Finding Solutions 6USING THE GAINS OF GROWTH 8Realizing <strong>the</strong> Growth Dividend 8Fiscal Policy for 1967 9Using <strong>the</strong> Growth Dividend 10RESTORING PRICE STABILITY 11INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC POLICIES 13Trade 13Aid 13Balance <strong>of</strong> Payments 14Improving <strong>the</strong> International Monetary System 16HELPING THE DISADVANTAGED 16Income Guarantees 17Public Assistance 17Training and Employment 18Social Security 18Unemployment Insurance 18CITIES AND HOUSING 19EDUCATION AND HEALTH 20ABATING POLLUTION 20IMPROVING OUR TAX SYSTEM 21IMPROVING GOVERNMENT ORGANIZATION 21OTHER ECONOMIC POLICIES 22AFTER VIETNAM 23CONCLUSION 24ANNUAL REPORT OF THE COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS*CHAPTER 1. EXTENDING THE RECORD OF PROSPERITY 37CHAPTER 2. PRICES AND WAGES IN 1966 72*For a detailed table <strong>of</strong> contents <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Council's <strong>Report</strong>, see page 81.m


PageCHAPTER 3. MAINTAINING PRICE STABILITY AND REDUCING UN-EMPLOYMENT 99CHAPTER 4. SELECTED USES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 135CHAPTER 5. GROWTH AND BALANCE IN THE WORLD ECONOMY 170APPENDIX A. REPORT TO THE PRESIDENT ON THE ACTIVITIES OFTHE COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS DURING 1966 199APPENDIX B. STATISTICAL TABLES RELATING TO INCOME, EMPLOY-MENT, AND PRODUCTION 207IV


ECONOMIC REPORTOF THE PRESIDENT


ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENTTo <strong>the</strong> Congress <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> United States:A healthy and productive economy is a bulwark <strong>of</strong> freedom.Around <strong>the</strong> world and here at home, our trials <strong>of</strong> strength, our works<strong>of</strong> peace, our quest for justice, our search for knowledge and understanding,our efforts to enrich our environment are buttressed by anamazing productive power.Americans have confronted many challenges in this century. The oneswe face in 1967 are as trying <strong>of</strong> men's spirits as any we have known. But<strong>the</strong> overwhelming majority <strong>of</strong> us face our challenges in comfort, if notaffluence. The sacrifices required <strong>of</strong> most <strong>of</strong> today's generation are not<strong>of</strong> income or security; ra<strong>the</strong>r we are called on to renounce prejudice,impatience, apathy, weakness, and weariness.In purely material terms, most Americans are better <strong>of</strong>f than everbefore. That fact expands our responsibilities, as it enlarges our resourcesto meet <strong>the</strong>m.RECENT ECONOMIC GAINSAn average <strong>of</strong> 74 million persons were at work in 1966—2 millionmore than in 1965. Nonfarm payrolls averaged 64 million, a gain <strong>of</strong>3 million. On <strong>the</strong> whole, <strong>the</strong>se jobs were better paying than ever, andmore regular and more secure than most workers can remember.The value <strong>of</strong> our total production <strong>of</strong> goods and services in 1966 was$740 billion—$58 billion, or 8/ 2 percent, higher than in 1965. More<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> increase than we wanted represented higher prices. Still, <strong>the</strong>gain was nearly 5 1 / 2 percent after correction for price changes.Labor, business, and <strong>the</strong> farmer all contributed to this major gain inproduction, and <strong>the</strong>y rightly shared <strong>the</strong> benefits.Aggregate compensation <strong>of</strong> employees rose 10.3 percent. Averagecompensation per man-hour in <strong>the</strong> private economy rose 6.5 percent, reflectingincreased wages and fringe benefits, more overtime, <strong>the</strong> shift tohigher-paying jobs, and increased employer contributions to Social Security.Corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its after taxes advanced more than 8 percent; per


dollar <strong>of</strong> sales <strong>the</strong>y were roughly unchanged from <strong>the</strong> high rate <strong>of</strong> 1965.Net income per farm rose more than 10 percent.The single most meaningful measure <strong>of</strong> economic well-being is realdisposable income per person—<strong>the</strong> after-tax purchasing power in stabledollars, available on <strong>the</strong> average to every man, woman, and child. Itrose 3/ 2 percent or $89 per person in 1966. Although this advance wassomewhat smaller than in 1965, it was still three times as large as <strong>the</strong>average yearly gain in <strong>the</strong> 1950's.February 1961 launched <strong>the</strong> strongest and most durable economicexpansion in our economic annals, and it still continues.• Almost 9 million jobs have been added in <strong>the</strong> last 6 years.• The rate <strong>of</strong> unemployment has fallen from 7 percent in early 1961to under 4 percent. The rate for white adult males fell from 5percent to 2 percent; for Negro men, from nearly 12 percent toless than 5 percent.• Early in 1961, more than two-thirds <strong>of</strong> our major labor marketswere "areas <strong>of</strong> substantial unemployment"; today only 8 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>150 are so classified, and 66 have unemployment below 3 percent.• While total population rose 11 million between 1961 and 1965,<strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> Americans in poverty declined 5^4 million, andprobably fell at least ano<strong>the</strong>r 1*4 million in 1966. (The povertydefinition is adjusted for <strong>the</strong> increase in living costs.)• Our gross national product (GNP) has grown 50 percent in 6years. In constant prices, <strong>the</strong> gain has averaged 5J/2 percent ayear. The physical output <strong>of</strong> our factories and mines is up over50 percent.• Private output per man-hour in 1966 was 19 percent higher thanin 1961.• The 6-year addition to our gross stock <strong>of</strong> private productivecapital—machines, buildings, transportation equipment, landimprovements, and inventories—is valued at $220 billion.• American families have added $470 billion to <strong>the</strong>ir accumulatedfinancial assets. They have added $150 billion to <strong>the</strong>ir debts.So <strong>the</strong>ir net financial position is $320 billion stronger than 6 yearsago.OUR ECONOMIC PROBLEMSProsperity is everywhere evident. But prosperity is never withoutproblems, and—in 1966—some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m were serious.


SOME LEADING PROBLEMS1. <strong>Economic</strong> progress still left far too many behind.• Nearly 3 million workers were without jobs at <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> 1966.Perhaps two-thirds <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m were "frictionally" unemployed:new entrants to <strong>the</strong> labor force in <strong>the</strong> process <strong>of</strong> locating a job;persons who quit one job to seek ano<strong>the</strong>r; workers in <strong>the</strong> "<strong>of</strong>f"months <strong>of</strong> seasonal industries; those temporarily laid <strong>of</strong>f but withinstructions to return. Their unemployment will be temporary;many were drawing unemployment insurance.# But most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> remaining third will wait a long time for a steadyjob. They are <strong>the</strong> "hard-core" unemployed—lacking <strong>the</strong> necessaryskills to find o<strong>the</strong>r than intermittent work; <strong>the</strong> victims <strong>of</strong> pastor present discrimination; those unable or unwilling to movefrom depressed areas and occupations; <strong>the</strong> physically or emotionallyhandicapped.# Ano<strong>the</strong>r half million to one million potential workers were noteven counted as unemployed. Many had long ago abandonedany search for a job. Some had never tried.• But even among those who worked year-round, some 2 millionbreadwinners—particularly <strong>the</strong> low-skilled with large families—earned incomes insufficient to support a minimum standard <strong>of</strong>decent subsistence.* And 63/2 million families were poor because <strong>the</strong> heads <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>irhouseholds were unable to work: ei<strong>the</strong>r aged, severely handicapped,or a widowed or deserted mo<strong>the</strong>r with young children.Those left behind used to be called <strong>the</strong> "invisible poor." But anawakened public conscience has sharpened <strong>the</strong> vision <strong>of</strong> most Americans.2. Price increases—although less than in many comparable periods—still were greater than we wanted or should long tolerate.It is tempting to blame <strong>the</strong> creep <strong>of</strong> prices on <strong>the</strong> greed <strong>of</strong> producers—or <strong>the</strong> irresponsibility <strong>of</strong> labor—or Government policies—or badwea<strong>the</strong>r—or economic disturbances abroad. Some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> price rise mayhave been due to each. But <strong>the</strong> main causes lay elsewhere:• Some can be traced to imbalances created by <strong>the</strong> special pressures<strong>of</strong> Vietnam procurement and booming private investment.# The spurt <strong>of</strong> demand—partly real, partly psychological—that followed<strong>the</strong> step-up <strong>of</strong> our Vietnam effort in mid-1965 simply exceeded<strong>the</strong> speed limits on <strong>the</strong> economy's ability to adjust. Ourresources were sufficient for <strong>the</strong> task; but <strong>the</strong> sheer speed <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>advance strained <strong>the</strong> ability <strong>of</strong> industrial management to mobilizeresources at <strong>the</strong> required pace.


• Some price advance was <strong>the</strong> inevitable cost <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> adjustmentsrequired in recovering from a decade <strong>of</strong> slack:—Wages had to be raised sharply in underpaid occupations,which previously held <strong>the</strong>ir labor only because <strong>the</strong> alternativewas no job at all.—Producers in once stagnant, low-pr<strong>of</strong>it industries saw opportunitiesfor expansion and found it possible to raise prices andearnings in order to attract needed capital.—Demand pressed harder on skilled occupations and pr<strong>of</strong>essionalservices where we had trained too few persons tomeet <strong>the</strong> needs <strong>of</strong> a high employment economy.Some price increases would still have occurred had we moved at asteadier pace.But <strong>the</strong>se price increases could have come slowly enough and have beensmall enough not to threaten a chain reaction <strong>of</strong> wages chasing o<strong>the</strong>rwages—wages chasing prices—prices chasing wages—and prices chasingo<strong>the</strong>r prices.It is this spiral we must and can avoid. But it will require responsibleaction on <strong>the</strong> part <strong>of</strong> all.3. Achieving equilibrium in our balance <strong>of</strong> payments remained a problem,in spite <strong>of</strong> strong new measures.The costs <strong>of</strong> Vietnam required us to spend many more hundreds <strong>of</strong>millions <strong>of</strong> dollars beyond our shores. At <strong>the</strong> same time, <strong>the</strong> spurt <strong>of</strong>demand caused our imports—especially <strong>of</strong> capital goods—to soar.We are determined to continue our progress toward equilibrium.4. Tight money and high interest rates concentrated <strong>the</strong> burden<strong>of</strong> restraint on housing.Interest rates in 1966 were as high as at any time in 40 years. Theywere pushed <strong>the</strong>re by an insatiable demand for credit, straining against adeliberately restricted supply. Monetary policy in 1966—like taxpolicy—was properly aimed at slowing down an economy expanding to<strong>of</strong>ast.The brakes applied last year worked. But tight money worked painfullyand inequitably. It cut construction by more than $8 billionduring 1966. Its impact was equivalent to a heavy across-<strong>the</strong>-board taxincrease, but with most <strong>of</strong> its effect concentrated on a single industry.FINDING SOLUTIONSWe will move this year toward solutions for <strong>the</strong>se problems and o<strong>the</strong>rs.But <strong>the</strong>y cannot all be completely solved in 1967.


Lifting <strong>the</strong> Burden on HousingNow that <strong>the</strong> economy's advance is again more moderate, <strong>the</strong> burden<strong>of</strong> tight money is being lifted. Interest rates are still extremely high—but <strong>the</strong>y are moving down from <strong>the</strong>ir peaks. Credit is still not readilyavailable to all who can make sound and productive use <strong>of</strong> it—but it isbecoming easier to get. More savings are flowing into our thrift institutionsand are beginning to be available to builders and homebuyers.The steps we took last year and those I am now proposing, <strong>the</strong> steps<strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve has recently taken and is continuing to take to increasecredit availability and lower interest rates, should have our housingindustry moving smartly forward by <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> 1967, and ready for one<strong>of</strong> its best years in 1968.Restoring Price StabilityThe advance <strong>of</strong> prices has already begun to slow. Wholesale pricesin December were below <strong>the</strong>ir levels <strong>of</strong> August.The more moderate pace <strong>of</strong> economic advance, now underway, which<strong>the</strong> policies I am recommending are designed to maintain, shouldfur<strong>the</strong>r diminish inflationary pressures.We cannot rescind all <strong>of</strong> last year's increases in costs, some <strong>of</strong> whichare still spreading through our structure <strong>of</strong> prices. Price stability cannotbe restored overnight. But we will be making good progress towardprice stability this year.Improving Our International PaymentsWe have recently announced stronger voluntary balance <strong>of</strong> paymentsprograms for 1967. Our policies to constrain economic expansion to asustainable pace should permit an improved export surplus.I am now recommending fur<strong>the</strong>r steps to streng<strong>the</strong>n our external payments.Yet so long as we remain heavily engaged in Sou<strong>the</strong>ast Asia,we will have a balance <strong>of</strong> payments problem.Combating PovertyWe will continue to attack poverty and deprivation through suchweapons as—Community Action and Head Start;—rent supplements and child nutrition;—aid to elementary and secondary education in poverty areas and<strong>the</strong> Teachers Corps;—<strong>the</strong> Manpower Development and Training Act, <strong>the</strong> Job Corps,<strong>the</strong> Neighborhood Youth Corps;—Medicare, Medicaid, and neighborhood health centers;—measures to end discrimination in jobs, education, and publicfacilities;


—<strong>the</strong> expanded coverage enacted last year for a higher minimumwage.I am proposing that our attack be reinforced with new weapons in1967.Yet, with old weapons and new, <strong>the</strong> war on poverty will not be wonin 1967—or 1968. There is no wonder drug which can suddenly conquerthis ancient scourge <strong>of</strong> man. It will be a long and continuingstruggle, which will challenge our imagination, our patience, our knowledge,and our resources for years to come. Our capacity to stay with<strong>the</strong> task will be a test <strong>of</strong> our maturity as a people.USING THE GAINS OF GROWTHFrom early 1961 to <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> 1966, our GNP rose an average <strong>of</strong> $44billion a year. About $9 billion a year was price increase. Of <strong>the</strong>balance• An average real gain <strong>of</strong> $10 billion a year (in 1966 prices) camefrom putting idle men and machines back to work.• An average real gain <strong>of</strong> $25 billion a year (in 1966 prices) camefrom <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> our resources: a larger work force, more andbetter capital and management, higher productivity.Fur<strong>the</strong>r gains from putting idle resources to work will now be harderto achieve.But our annual dividend from growth has meanwhile become moregenerous. In 1967 it will add $30 billion at today's prices to our potentialoutput.Our economic policies must assure that we realize this potentialdividend—and use it wisely.REALIZING THE GROWTH DIVIDENDTo ensure our full dividend from economic growth requires thatmarkets for goods and services expand steadily and adequately—butnot excessively. In recent years, we have tested and refined <strong>the</strong> power<strong>of</strong> fiscal and monetary policy to stimulate or moderate <strong>the</strong> expansion<strong>of</strong> total demand.During 1966, Federal expenditures were expanding rapidly. But taxpolicy worked to counter <strong>the</strong>ir impact.Federal expenditures in our national income accounts grew $19billion in calendar year 1966, reflecting <strong>the</strong> step-up in national defense;in Social Security, Medicare, and related payments; and in grants toState and local governments. They added strongly to private pur-8


chasing power. They would have added more but for <strong>the</strong> substantialexpenditure cutbacks put into effect during <strong>the</strong> year.On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r side, taxes restrained demand. Higher payroll taxes,<strong>the</strong> restoration <strong>of</strong> some excise taxes, <strong>the</strong> institution <strong>of</strong> graduated withholding,and <strong>the</strong> suspension <strong>of</strong> tax incentives to investment all representednew measures that were draining <strong>of</strong>f more than $9 billion <strong>of</strong>spendable incomes by year-end. In combination, and for <strong>the</strong> full year,<strong>the</strong>se measures and an expanding economy produced $18 billion morein revenues than in 1965. Prompt action by Congress in response to mytax proposals <strong>of</strong> January and September made tax policy an importantforce for economic restraint.Taking <strong>the</strong> two sides toge<strong>the</strong>r, our national income accounts budgetwas in surplus in <strong>the</strong> first half and in balance for 1966 as a whole.But as private investment threatened to outrun private saving, sharpmonetary restraint was also applied. In response to both fiscal andmonetary restraints, <strong>the</strong> economy shifted gears from excessive speed toa moderate advance.FISCAL POLICY FOR 1967In <strong>the</strong> year ahead we are determined to maintain that moderateadvance; we need no fur<strong>the</strong>r slowdown; we can tolerate no new spurt<strong>of</strong> demand. After midyear, <strong>the</strong> tax increase I have proposed and amore moderate growth <strong>of</strong> Federal spending will increase <strong>the</strong> freedom <strong>of</strong>monetary policy to support expansion. I am confident that <strong>the</strong> opportunitywill be used.The specific fiscal program I am recommending includes—a surcharge <strong>of</strong> 6 percent on <strong>the</strong> tax liabilities <strong>of</strong> individuals,exempting persons in <strong>the</strong> lowest income brackets;—<strong>the</strong> same 6 percent surcharge on <strong>the</strong> tax liabilities <strong>of</strong> corporations.Here are some examples <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> effect <strong>of</strong> this proposal, as applied toa married couple with two dependents, using typical deductions:• With $5,000 income, <strong>the</strong>ir tax will be unchanged—still $130lower than <strong>the</strong>y would have paid in 1963.• With $10,000 income, <strong>the</strong>ir tax in 1968 will rise $67, or $1.30a week. Their annual tax will still be $190 less than <strong>the</strong>y wouldhave paid in 1963.• With $20,000 income, <strong>the</strong>ir tax in 1968 will rise $190, or $3.65a week. But <strong>the</strong>ir annual tax will still be $450 less than <strong>the</strong>ywould have paid in 1963.A corporation with pr<strong>of</strong>its before tax <strong>of</strong> $100,000 will pay an extra$2,490. It will still pay $2,510 less than it would have paid in 1963.


One with pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>of</strong> $1,000,000 will pay an extra $28,410, still $12,590less than it would have paid in 1963.The surcharge will provide for $5.1 billion <strong>of</strong> extra revenues in fiscalyear 1968 on a national income accounts basis, substantially <strong>of</strong>fsetting<strong>the</strong> expansion <strong>of</strong> $5.8 billion in defense purchases.The national income accounts budget will also be affected by my proposalsfor Social Security benefits and taxes.After allowance for <strong>the</strong>se changes, <strong>the</strong> national income accounts deficitfor fiscal year 1968 is now estimated at $2.1 billion, compared with$3.8 billion in fiscal year 1967.I am also recommending two fur<strong>the</strong>r accelerations <strong>of</strong> corporate taxpayments, to begin in 1968:—requiring quarterly payment <strong>of</strong> estimated tax on <strong>the</strong> basis <strong>of</strong> 80percent ra<strong>the</strong>r than 70 percent <strong>of</strong> liability;—requiring, over a 5-year period, that small corporations, as wellas large, become current in <strong>the</strong>ir tax payments, in <strong>the</strong> same wayas individual proprietors.We have fashioned a fiscal program for sustainable expansion. Withthat program, we now see a rise <strong>of</strong> about $47 billion in our GNP in1967—a growth dividend close to 4 percent in real terms.USING THE GROWTH DIVIDENDThe first priority for <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> our growth dividend must, as always,be <strong>the</strong> defense <strong>of</strong> freedom. But it will take only a small part <strong>of</strong> our $47billion <strong>of</strong> added production.These will be <strong>the</strong> public claims on our growth dividend:* $10 billion more <strong>of</strong> our output in 1967 will go for <strong>the</strong> support <strong>of</strong>our men in Vietnam and o<strong>the</strong>r urgent needs <strong>of</strong> defense.• $1 y 2 billion will go for <strong>the</strong> expansion <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r Federal purchases,including adjustments in Federal civilian and military pay.# State and local governments will use about $8 billion more <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Nation's resources in 1967. In this, <strong>the</strong>y will be aided by Federalgrants totaling nearly $15 billion.The remaining $27^ billion <strong>of</strong> our GNP gain in 1967—nearly 60percent <strong>of</strong> it—will be used in <strong>the</strong> private sector. And <strong>the</strong> flow <strong>of</strong> goodsand services to consumers will expand this year by even more than that.• In <strong>the</strong> past several years, an unusually large part <strong>of</strong> our outputgrowth has gone to expand <strong>the</strong> productive capacity <strong>of</strong> businessand to build up inventories to support high and growing productionand sales. On balance, a slightly smaller portion <strong>of</strong> our resourceswill be used for <strong>the</strong>se purposes in 1967 than in 1966.IO


• For <strong>the</strong> year as a whole, slightly less <strong>of</strong> our resources than lastyear will be used to build new homes, although a sharp recoveryin residential construction from its current deep recession isexpected during <strong>the</strong> course <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year.As <strong>the</strong> flow <strong>of</strong> goods and services to consumers expands, <strong>the</strong> ability <strong>of</strong>our elderly citizens to share in <strong>the</strong>se gains will be supported by a rise <strong>of</strong>more than $6 billion in Social Security and Medicare payments.In 1967, we will have no bonus dividend from using previously idleresources. But <strong>the</strong> dividend from growth alone is a big one. We mustbe sure we get it; and we must use it wisely.RESTORING PRICE STABILITYFrom <strong>the</strong> beginning <strong>of</strong> 1961 until 1965, <strong>the</strong> United States enjoyedboth price stability and a strongly expanding economy. The average <strong>of</strong>wholesale prices hardly moved, and consumer prices rose only a littlemore than 1 percent a year. Last year, that record was blemished.Consumer prices rose 2.9 percent between 1965 and 1966, wholesaleprices 3.2 percent.When we were involved in Korea, consumer prices rose 8.0 percentbetween 1950 and 1951, wholesale prices 11.4 percent. And we hadprice controls during most <strong>of</strong> 1951.Even when we were not at war, consumer prices rose 3.5 percentbetween 1956 and 1957, wholesale prices 2.9 percent.Never<strong>the</strong>less, we are not satisfied with our record on prices. And weexpect to improve on it this year.There are many reasons why we refuse to tolerate rapidly rising prices:• They injure those with fixed incomes, especially older people.• They can lead to speculation and economic distortions whichcould undermine prosperity.• They weaken our competitive position in world markets.• As <strong>the</strong>y persist, <strong>the</strong>y become harder to stop without throwing <strong>the</strong>economy into reverse.Restoring price stability is one <strong>of</strong> our major tasks. It will not be accomplishedall at once, or all in 1967. That could be done—if at all—only at <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> mass unemployment, idle machines, and intolerableeconomic waste. But a gradual return to stability can go hand in handwith steady economic advance.Such an improvement will require—prudent fiscal and monetary policies;—Government efforts to help relieve <strong>the</strong> key points <strong>of</strong> pressure onprices;II


—<strong>the</strong> responsible conduct <strong>of</strong> those in business and labor who have<strong>the</strong> power to make price and wage decisions.With steady, sustainable, and balanced growth, we can look forwardto—relief <strong>of</strong> pressures on capacity in such strained areas as machineryand metals;—adjustments <strong>of</strong> raw materials supplies to demand;—<strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> labor shortages in key areas.O<strong>the</strong>r efforts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Government can help to relieve particularpressures on prices and wages. We will continue—to develop manpower training programs to meet skill shortages;—to increase <strong>the</strong> efficiency <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> employment services in matchingjobs and men;—to handle Government procurement so as to minimize its pressureon prices;—to dispose <strong>of</strong> surplus Government stockpiles to alleviate shortages<strong>of</strong> raw materials;—to manage farm programs to assure adequate supplies as wellas equitable returns.But efforts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Government alone will not be enough. The cooperation<strong>of</strong> business and labor is essential for success.In <strong>the</strong> past year, most businessmen who had a choice in setting pricesand most trade unions that negotiated wage contracts acted responsibly.They did so because <strong>the</strong>y took account <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> national interest andsaw that it was also <strong>the</strong>ir own.If business and labor were to consider only <strong>the</strong>ir own short-run interests—each union might seek a wage increase which exceeds <strong>the</strong> mostrecent settlement by some o<strong>the</strong>r union;—each business might strive to achieve a new pr<strong>of</strong>it record by translatingstrong demand into higher prices, whe<strong>the</strong>r or not costshave increased.But when business and labor consider <strong>the</strong> national interest—and <strong>the</strong>irown longer-run interests—<strong>the</strong>y realize that such actions would have onlyone result: a wage-price spiral which is in <strong>the</strong> interest <strong>of</strong> nei<strong>the</strong>r.• If unions now attempt to recoup in wages all <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> past or anticipatedadvance in <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> living—in addition to <strong>the</strong> productivitytrend;• If businesses now seek to pass along rising costs when it would bepossible to absorb <strong>the</strong>m or do not reduce prices when costs fall;<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> result will be just such a spiral—damaging to business, damagingto labor, and disastrous to <strong>the</strong> Nation.12


Once again, I appeal to business and labor—in <strong>the</strong>ir own interest andthat <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Nation—for <strong>the</strong> utmost restraint and responsibility in wageand price decisions.INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC POLICIESThe current year is a critical one for our international economic policiesand for <strong>the</strong> economic progress <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> world community.As <strong>the</strong> largest single market and source <strong>of</strong> capital, <strong>the</strong> United Statescarries special responsibilities.TRADEThis Administration is committed to reducing barriers to internationaltrade, as demonstrated by my recent action terminating <strong>the</strong> 1954escape clause action on watches, and rolling back <strong>the</strong> special tariff onimports <strong>of</strong> glass.The Kennedy Round <strong>of</strong> trade negotiations is now entering its final andmost critical phase. I emphasize once more how important this greatattempt to liberalize world trade is for all <strong>the</strong> developed and developingnations <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> free world.After more than 4 years <strong>of</strong> discussion, it is essential that <strong>the</strong> participantsnow resolve <strong>the</strong> many complex problems that still remain. It wouldindeed be a tragedy if <strong>the</strong> wide authority granted to <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> by <strong>the</strong>Trade Expansion Act <strong>of</strong> 1962 were allowed to lapse unused. Neverbefore has <strong>the</strong>re been such a splendid opportunity to increase world trade.It must not be lost.But <strong>the</strong> Kennedy Round is not <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> road. We must lookbeyond <strong>the</strong> negotiations in Geneva to fur<strong>the</strong>r progress in <strong>the</strong> years ahead.We must begin to shape a trade policy for <strong>the</strong> next decade that is responsiveto <strong>the</strong> needs <strong>of</strong> both <strong>the</strong> less developed and <strong>the</strong> advanced countries.We should seize every opportunity to build and enlarge bridges <strong>of</strong>peaceful exchange with <strong>the</strong> countries <strong>of</strong> Eastern Europe and <strong>the</strong> SovietUnion. We should have <strong>the</strong> ability to adapt our policies to whateverpolitical circumstances or commercial opportunities may present <strong>the</strong>mselves.I again urge <strong>the</strong> Congress to provide authority to expand ourtrade relations with Eastern Europe and <strong>the</strong> Soviet Union.AIDAlthough 1966 was a relatively good year for world economic growth,average output in developing countries rose by less than $3 a person.240-782 0—67—213


There were, however, encouraging signs <strong>of</strong> progress. Developingnations demonstrated a willingness to take difficult but necessary stepsto help <strong>the</strong>mselves. India, for example, revised her foreign exchangeand agricultural policies to promote more rapid growth.Among <strong>the</strong> wealthier nations, stronger efforts were made to assist <strong>the</strong>development <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> poorer countries. Canada and Japan increased<strong>the</strong>ir assistance programs. Major free world aid donors joined in newgroups to coordinate <strong>the</strong>ir flow<strong>of</strong> aid.The United States will continue to respond constructively to <strong>the</strong> aspirations<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> developing nations. We will give first priority to fighting <strong>the</strong>evils <strong>of</strong> hunger, disease, and ignorance in those free world countrieswhich are resolutely committed to helping <strong>the</strong>mselves.There should, however, be increasing efforts to make both <strong>the</strong> receivingand giving <strong>of</strong> aid a matter for creative international partnership.We shall <strong>the</strong>refore—continue to support enthusiastically, in a manner consistentwith our balance <strong>of</strong> payments position, such promising cooperativeregional efforts as <strong>the</strong> Alliance for Progress, <strong>the</strong> Inter-American,<strong>the</strong> Asian, and <strong>the</strong> African Development Banks, and <strong>the</strong>Mekong Development Fund <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> United Nations;—fur<strong>the</strong>r encourage <strong>the</strong> coordinated extension and expansion <strong>of</strong>aid by <strong>the</strong> major donor countries in ways that result in anequitable sharing <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> burden;—seek <strong>the</strong> cooperation <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r major donor countries this year inreplenishing <strong>the</strong> resources <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> International Development Association.BALANCE OF PAYMENTSWe can take some satisfaction in <strong>the</strong> fact that our balance <strong>of</strong> paymentsin 1966 may prove to have been in surplus on <strong>of</strong>ficial reserve settlements.Despite <strong>the</strong> added costs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> war in Vietnam and <strong>the</strong> rapid growth <strong>of</strong>imports, our deficit on a liquidity basis increased only slightly in 1966.But we cannot relax our efforts to seek fur<strong>the</strong>r improvement.Our goal in <strong>the</strong> coming year is to continue to move toward balance <strong>of</strong>payments equilibrium as rapidly as <strong>the</strong> foreign exchange costs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Vietnam conflict may permit. This goal will be supported throughmeasures and policies consistent with healthy growth at home and ourresponsibilities abroad.We already have extended and reinforced <strong>the</strong> voluntary restraint programsfor corporate investment abroad and for foreign lending byfinancial institutions. I am counting on <strong>the</strong> continued full cooperation<strong>of</strong> businesses and banks with <strong>the</strong>se programs in 1967. And I have14


instructed all agencies <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Government to intensify <strong>the</strong>ir efforts to limit<strong>the</strong> dollar drain resulting from <strong>the</strong>ir activities.But more is needed. I now recommend <strong>the</strong> following steps:1. The Congress should extend <strong>the</strong> Interest Equalization Tax, instreng<strong>the</strong>ned form, to July 31, 1969. This tax has proved extremelyuseful in limiting <strong>the</strong> borrowing <strong>of</strong> developed countries inour capital markets and in reinforcing <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve voluntaryprogram. As we move toward easier money in <strong>the</strong> UnitedStates, foreign borrowing in our financial markets may tend toincrease. I am <strong>the</strong>refore requesting authority to adjust <strong>the</strong>rates <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Interest Equalization Tax as monetary conditionswarrant, so that <strong>the</strong> effective impact on interest costs can be variedbetween zero and 2 percent. This would replace <strong>the</strong> present flat1-percent impact.Moreover, to ensure against possible anticipatory increases inforeign borrowing, I am also requesting that <strong>the</strong> tax be imposedat rates which provide an impact <strong>of</strong> 2 percent on interest costswhile <strong>the</strong> legislation is under consideration by Congress.2. The most satisfactory way to arrest <strong>the</strong> increasing gap betweenAmerican travel abroad and foreign travel here is not to limit<strong>the</strong> former but to stimulate and encourage <strong>the</strong> latter. I shallappoint in <strong>the</strong> near future a special industry-Government taskforce to make specific recommendations by May 1, 1967, onhow <strong>the</strong> Federal Government can best stimulate foreign travelto <strong>the</strong> United States. After a careful review <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir advice,I shall ask <strong>the</strong> U.S. Travel Service and o<strong>the</strong>r appropriate agenciesto take <strong>the</strong> steps that seem most promising.3. As part <strong>of</strong> our long-run balance <strong>of</strong> payments program, I shallalso—request continuation and expansion by $4.5 billion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>lending authority <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Export-Import Bank in order tosupport <strong>the</strong> expansion <strong>of</strong> exports;—continue to urge o<strong>the</strong>r countries to participate in <strong>the</strong> development<strong>of</strong> better means both <strong>of</strong> sharing <strong>the</strong> resourceburdens and <strong>of</strong> neutralizing <strong>the</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> payments effectarising from <strong>the</strong> common defense and foreign assistanceefforts.4. For <strong>the</strong> longer run strength <strong>of</strong> our payments balance, we shouldintensify efforts to—stimulate exporters' interest in supplying foreign markets;—enlist <strong>the</strong> support <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> financial community to attractadditional foreign investment in <strong>the</strong> United States;—encourage fur<strong>the</strong>r development <strong>of</strong> foreign capital markets.15


IMPROVING THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEMIn 1966, significant progress was made toward a better internationalmonetary system. Through close consultation and cooperation among<strong>the</strong> financial authorities <strong>of</strong> major countries, temporary strains were metpromptly and effectively.Two large forward steps were taken on <strong>the</strong> road to international monetaryreform: wide consensus was reached on basic principles for <strong>the</strong>deliberate creation <strong>of</strong> additional reserve assets; and <strong>the</strong> negotiationsadvanced to a second stage in which all members <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> InternationalMonetary Fund are participating.An even greater effort must be made in <strong>the</strong> coming year to improveour monetary system. In particular, I urge that—all countries participate in <strong>the</strong> continuing task <strong>of</strong> streng<strong>the</strong>ning<strong>the</strong> basic monetary arrangements that have served <strong>the</strong> world sowell;—both surplus and deficit countries assume <strong>the</strong>ir full responsibilityfor proper adjustment <strong>of</strong> international payments imbalances, andcooperate in efforts to lower world interest rates;—full agreement be reached on a constructive contingency planfor <strong>the</strong> adequate and orderly growth <strong>of</strong> world monetary reserves.HELPING THE DISADVANTAGEDThe United States is <strong>the</strong> first large nation in <strong>the</strong> history <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> worldwealthy enough to end poverty within its borders. There are manyfronts in <strong>the</strong> War on Poverty. We are moving forward on <strong>the</strong>m all.• There must be full employment so that those qualified and ableto work can find jobs. . . . The unemployment rate last yearwas <strong>the</strong> lowest in 13 years.• Those not now fully qualified must be given <strong>the</strong> education andtraining, <strong>the</strong> health and guidance services which will enable <strong>the</strong>mto make <strong>the</strong>ir full contribution to society. . . . We have greatlyincreased our aid to education and enlarged our training programs,and we will expand <strong>the</strong>m fur<strong>the</strong>r.• For those who will be unable to earn adequate incomes, <strong>the</strong>remust be help—most <strong>of</strong> all for <strong>the</strong> benefit <strong>of</strong> children, whosemisfortune to be born poor must not deprive <strong>the</strong>m <strong>of</strong> future opportunity.. . . We have increased our income support, and wewill increase it fur<strong>the</strong>r.• Wherever <strong>the</strong> poor and disadvantaged are concentrated, intensiveand coordinated programs to break <strong>the</strong> cycle <strong>of</strong> deprivation16


and dependency must continue and be reinforced. . . . Weinstituted <strong>the</strong>se programs in hundreds <strong>of</strong> cities and rural areas;we are expanding <strong>the</strong>m and designing o<strong>the</strong>rs.INCOME GUARANTEESCompletely new proposals for guaranteeing minimum incomes arenow under discussion. They range from a "negative income tax" to acomplete restructuring <strong>of</strong> Public Assistance to a program <strong>of</strong> residualpublic employment for all who lack private jobs. Their advocatesinclude some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> sturdiest defenders <strong>of</strong> free enterprise. These plansmay or may not prove to be practicable at any time. And <strong>the</strong>y arealmost surely beyond our means at this time. But we must examine anyplan, however unconventional, which could promise a major advance.I intend to establish a commission <strong>of</strong> leading Americans to examine <strong>the</strong>many proposals that have been put forward, reviewing <strong>the</strong>ir merits anddisadvantages, and reporting in 2 years to me and <strong>the</strong> American people.PUBLIC ASSISTANCEOur system <strong>of</strong> public assistance is now 30 years old and has obviousfaults. The standards <strong>of</strong> need set by many States are unrealisticallylow; benefits are fur<strong>the</strong>r restricted by excessively stringent eligibility conditions.In some respects <strong>the</strong> system perpetuates dependency.1. State standards <strong>of</strong> need are miserably low. In 18 States a family<strong>of</strong> 4 is presumed able to manage for a month on $45 a person—or less.And in many States, actual payments average far below <strong>the</strong>ir own standards<strong>of</strong> need.It is time to raise payments toward more acceptable levels.As a first step, I ask <strong>the</strong> Congress to require that each State's paymentsat least meet its own definition <strong>of</strong> need; and that its definitionshould be kept up to date annually as conditions change.2. With minor exceptions, payments under public assistance are reduceddollar for dollar <strong>of</strong> earnings by <strong>the</strong> recipient, removing any incentiveto accept part-time work. We should encourage self-help, notpenalize it.It is time to put an end to this 100 percent tax on <strong>the</strong> earnings <strong>of</strong>those on public assistance.I shall <strong>the</strong>refore ask Congress to enact payment formulas whichwill permit those on assistance to keep some part <strong>of</strong> what <strong>the</strong>y mayearn, without loss <strong>of</strong> payments.3. Many recipients <strong>of</strong> public assistance are capable <strong>of</strong> receiving trainingwhich would ultimately make <strong>the</strong>m self-supporting.17


I <strong>the</strong>refore urge <strong>the</strong> Congress to make permanent <strong>the</strong> UnemployedParent and Community Work and Training programs associatedwith Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC), and torequire all States receiving Federal support under AFDC to cooperatein making Community Work and Training available for <strong>the</strong>unemployed parents <strong>of</strong> dependent children.TRAINING AND EMPLOYMENTThe coexistence <strong>of</strong> job vacancies and idle workers unable to fill <strong>the</strong>mrepresents a bitter human tragedy and an inexcusable economic waste.One <strong>of</strong> society's most creative acts is <strong>the</strong> training <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> unemployed, <strong>the</strong>underemployed, or <strong>the</strong> formerly unemployable to fill those vacancies.A dynamic economy demands new and changing skills. By enablingworkers to acquire those skills, we open opportunities for individual developmentand self-fulfillment. And we make possible higher productionwithout inflationary pressures.I shall ask <strong>the</strong> Congress for funds to support a new and special effortto train and find jobs for <strong>the</strong> disadvantaged who live in urban ghettos.I shall also propose legislation to improve <strong>the</strong> effectiveness <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Federal-State employment service.SOCIAL SECURITYMillions <strong>of</strong> aged still live in poverty. Millions <strong>of</strong> younger Americansare willing to pay for more adequate retirement benefits in <strong>the</strong> future.I ask <strong>the</strong> Congress to approve an over-all 20 percent increase in ourSocial Security program. We can increase benefits for all Social Securitybeneficiaries by at least 15 percent, raise <strong>the</strong> minimum benefit by59 percent to $70 a month, assure workers with 25 years <strong>of</strong> coverageat least $100 a month, extend Medical Insurance to disabled beneficiaries,and allow larger earnings without loss <strong>of</strong> benefits.UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCEOur system <strong>of</strong> unemployment insurance was created in a world <strong>of</strong>massive unemployment. The needs <strong>of</strong> a high employment economy aredifferent. Today, when jobs are available, <strong>the</strong> jobless who exhaust <strong>the</strong>irbenefits typically need training, guidance, or o<strong>the</strong>r supportive services.Therefore, I am asking <strong>the</strong> Congress to consider legislation to providesuch services in conjunction with extended benefits to <strong>the</strong> long-termunemployed, to extend <strong>the</strong> protection <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> system to additional workers,to establish more uniformly adequate benefits, and to correct abuses.18


CITIES AND HOUSINGThe American city is not obsolete; it is still a great engine for economicand social progress. But cities are in trouble, threatened by congestion,pollution, crime, poverty, racial tension, slums, and blight.Yesterday's rural poor have been moving to <strong>the</strong> city just as many <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> jobs <strong>the</strong>y seek and need have been moving to <strong>the</strong> suburbs. Inadequatetransportation and discrimination in housing make it difficultfor <strong>the</strong>m to follow <strong>the</strong> jobs; and deficiencies <strong>of</strong> education, health,and skills compound <strong>the</strong>ir disadvantages.Most cities cannot afford <strong>the</strong> massive expenditures necessary to solve<strong>the</strong>se problems. The flight <strong>of</strong> higher income families and businessesto <strong>the</strong> suburbs erodes sources <strong>of</strong> revenue for <strong>the</strong> cities, even as expendituredemands escalate. Inflexible city limits have created a hodgepodge<strong>of</strong> local taxing jurisdictions, <strong>of</strong>ten dividing <strong>the</strong> tax base from <strong>the</strong> need.The cities cannot collect for <strong>the</strong> many benefits <strong>the</strong>y supply to residents<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> suburbs.The problems <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> cities flow across irrelevant boundaries establishedby historical accident. So solutions must draw on <strong>the</strong> resources andimagination <strong>of</strong> a larger area. Our efforts have been aimed to encouragea metropolitan approach to metropolitan problems.We must also find ways to enlist more fully <strong>the</strong> resources and. imagination<strong>of</strong> private enterprise in <strong>the</strong> great task <strong>of</strong> restoring our cities.I have just appointed a Commission, under <strong>the</strong> chairmanship <strong>of</strong>Senator Paul H. Douglas, to work with <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Housingand Urban Development to examine problems <strong>of</strong> codes, zoning, taxation,and development standards and to recommend ways to increase<strong>the</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> low-cost housing. I am convinced that this study canmake a major contribution to <strong>the</strong> solution <strong>of</strong> urban problems.Last year, <strong>the</strong> Congress enacted <strong>the</strong> pathbreaking Model Cities legislation.The Federal Government will help cities to focus all availableprograms on <strong>the</strong>ir needs—eventually to overwhelm <strong>the</strong> problems thathave heret<strong>of</strong>ore overwhelmed <strong>the</strong> cities.More than 70 cities will have completed <strong>the</strong>ir plans and be eligible tostart receiving assistance in 1968. Federal aid for water and sewerprojects, open land conservation, and urban mass transportation is encouraginga more coordinated approach to metropolitan problems. Iseek increased appropriations for all <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se programs. And I shallseek authorization and resources for a greatly expanded program <strong>of</strong>research on urban problems.19


Growth in <strong>the</strong> number and incomes <strong>of</strong> American families will requireus to build about 2 million new houses a year for <strong>the</strong> next decade,most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m in and around cities. Last year, housing bore a disproportionatepart <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> burden <strong>of</strong> needed restraint. But we are now movinginto a period <strong>of</strong> renewed homebuilding. I look for construction torise briskly during 1967.Federal programs for fiscal 1968 will assist in construction or renovation<strong>of</strong> 165,000 housing units for <strong>the</strong> urban poor, <strong>the</strong> elderly, and <strong>the</strong>handicapped. The Rent Supplement program will contribute to thisgoal.This year will be a brightening one for <strong>the</strong> housing industry; it canalso be a landmark year in <strong>the</strong> progress and evolution <strong>of</strong> our cities.EDUCATION AND HEALTHIndividually and collectively, Americans have insatiable appetites formore education and better health. Education and health contributeboth to individual well-being and to <strong>the</strong> Nation's productivity. But fartoo many <strong>of</strong> our urban and rural poor are denied adequate access toei<strong>the</strong>r. The efficiency <strong>of</strong> our methods <strong>of</strong> education and <strong>of</strong> providingmedical care can and should be streng<strong>the</strong>ned.History will record <strong>the</strong>se years as <strong>the</strong> time when this Nation awoke toits needs—and its limitations—in education and health. The Elementaryand Secondary Education Act, Head Start, <strong>the</strong> Teachers Corps,Medicare, Medicaid, and <strong>the</strong> Partnership in Health will be landmarksin our social and economic development.I shall propose—an expanded Head Start program; a Follow-Through programin <strong>the</strong> early years <strong>of</strong> school; and <strong>the</strong> opening <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r new educationalopportunities for children;—both legislative and administrative changes to accelerate researchand development on more efficient and effective ways <strong>of</strong> providinghealth resources;—an expanded child health program, including early diagnosis andtreatment, a pilot program <strong>of</strong> dental care, and <strong>the</strong> training <strong>of</strong> additionalhealth personnel to provide services to children.ABATING POLLUTIONA polluted environment erodes our health and well-being. It diminishesindividual vitality; it is costly to industry and agriculture; it has20


debilitating effects on urban and regional development; it takes some <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> joy out <strong>of</strong> life.The 89th Congress enacted important legislation to improve <strong>the</strong> quality<strong>of</strong> our environment. All 50 States have now signified <strong>the</strong>ir intentionto establish water quality standards for <strong>the</strong>ir interstate and coastal waters.The Federal Government is assisting State and local governments throughcomprehensive water basin planning, and is providing financial help toStates for <strong>the</strong> administration <strong>of</strong> water pollution control and to local areasfor <strong>the</strong> construction <strong>of</strong> sewage treatment facilities. In addition, we arestudying appropriate methods to encourage industry to control its discharge<strong>of</strong> pollutants.The foundation for abating air pollution was laid in <strong>the</strong> Clean AirAct <strong>of</strong> 1965. But <strong>the</strong> air over every city proves that fur<strong>the</strong>r steps arenecessary.I propose that we get on with <strong>the</strong> jobs <strong>of</strong> preserving and restoring ourenvironment. I will present detailed proposals on control <strong>of</strong> air pollutionin ano<strong>the</strong>r message.IMPROVING OUR TAX SYSTEMOur tax system is one in which we can take pride. In terms <strong>of</strong>fairness, revenue productivity, and balanced economic impact, it isunsurpassed by any o<strong>the</strong>r tax system in <strong>the</strong> world today.Never<strong>the</strong>less, it can be improved. As <strong>the</strong>y now stand, our tax lawsimpose undue burdens on some and grant unfair benefits to o<strong>the</strong>rs.A system as complex as ours cannot be perfected in a single bill.Ra<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> process <strong>of</strong> tax reform must be continuous, with everyprovision <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> law subject to constant examination and adjustmentwhere needed. Moreover, this work <strong>of</strong> basic reform should proceedindependently <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> requirements for raising taxes or <strong>the</strong> opportunitiesfor tax reduction.I <strong>the</strong>refore plan to submit proposals to <strong>the</strong> Congress to improve <strong>the</strong>equity <strong>of</strong> our tax system and reduce economic distortions. These proposalswill be designed to avoid significant budgetary effects.As one specific reform, I will urge changes to deal with abuses bytax-exempt private foundations.IMPROVING GOVERNMENT ORGANIZATIONSeparate Departments <strong>of</strong> Labor and Commerce perpetuate <strong>the</strong> obsoletenotion that <strong>the</strong>re is fundamental conflict between <strong>the</strong> interests <strong>of</strong> businessand labor, or between <strong>the</strong> interests <strong>of</strong> ei<strong>the</strong>r and that <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Nation.21


A single department <strong>of</strong> labor and business can more effectively carryout those national programs which affect <strong>the</strong> private productive sectoras a whole. The two departments share many common objectives; <strong>the</strong>irinterests and activities coincide or overlap in—fostering economic and regional development;—matching <strong>the</strong> skills <strong>of</strong> labor with <strong>the</strong> needs <strong>of</strong> employers;—providing more jobs at better wages;—avoiding labor disputes;—maintaining a fair distribution <strong>of</strong> private incomes without inflation;—providing stability <strong>of</strong> production and jobs;—providing basic economic and social information and technicalservices needed by both private and public sectors;—supporting expansion <strong>of</strong> international trade and considering itsimpact on <strong>the</strong> domestic economy.By combining <strong>the</strong>se activities, we can greatly improve efficiency, reducecosts, simplify <strong>the</strong> reporting burden on business, provide betterand more uniform statistics, and assure that <strong>the</strong> views and <strong>the</strong> problems<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> private sector enter more effectively into decisions on general economicpolicy.I urge <strong>the</strong> Congress to support my recommendation for a new department<strong>of</strong> labor and business.OTHER ECONOMIC POLICIES1. I renew four recommendations made in my <strong>Economic</strong> <strong>Report</strong> <strong>of</strong>1966 and not acted upon by <strong>the</strong> 89th Congress:—a fair system <strong>of</strong> charges for users <strong>of</strong> highways, aviation facilities,and inland waterways, to improve efficiency in <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> transportationresources, and to reimburse <strong>the</strong> Federal Governmentfor a part <strong>of</strong> its expenditures on facilities which directly benefitthose who use <strong>the</strong>m;—truth-in-lending legislation, to provide consumers with a full andclear statement <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> true cost <strong>of</strong> credit;—stronger regulation <strong>of</strong> savings and loan holding companies;—provision <strong>of</strong> Federal charters for mutual savings banks, to enlargeand streng<strong>the</strong>n our system <strong>of</strong> thrift institutions.2. To aid <strong>the</strong> advance <strong>of</strong> technology on which economic progress depends,I now urge Congressional support for—a long-overdue modernization <strong>of</strong> our patent system;—a large-scale program <strong>of</strong> research in transportation.22


3. Total holdings in <strong>the</strong> Nation's stockpile <strong>of</strong> strategic and criticalmaterials now stand at $6.5 billion. Of this amount, $3.4 billion are excessto our defense needs as presently determined.During <strong>the</strong> last fiscal year, <strong>the</strong> Administrator <strong>of</strong> General Services disposed<strong>of</strong> excess stockpile materials valued at slightly more than $1 billionwithout disruption <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> domestic economy or <strong>the</strong> normal channels <strong>of</strong>trade.The last session <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Congress authorized disposal <strong>of</strong> excess stockpilematerial valued at $782 million. I will ask <strong>the</strong> Congress for authorityto dispose <strong>of</strong> additional stockpile excesses, bringing to about $2 billion <strong>the</strong>present value <strong>of</strong> excess stockpile material available for disposal.I believe that we should relieve taxpayers <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> burden <strong>of</strong> carrying unneededsurplus stocks, and provide businesses and workers with <strong>the</strong> materialsnecessary to assure continued high levels <strong>of</strong> production.4. The responsibility which we share with <strong>the</strong> States to ensure thatour banks and thrift institutions are honest, competent, and competitiveis a continuing function demanding constant attention. We must continueto encourage <strong>the</strong> orderly and progressive development <strong>of</strong> a financialsystem adequate to meet <strong>the</strong> needs <strong>of</strong> a growing and dynamic economy.I urge <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve Board, <strong>the</strong> Federal Deposit InsuranceCorporation, <strong>the</strong> Comptroller <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Currency, and <strong>the</strong> Federal HomeLoan Bank Board to continue and to intensify <strong>the</strong>ir efforts to coordinate<strong>the</strong>ir regulatory policies and procedures, and to improve <strong>the</strong>ir examinationmethods.AFTER VIETNAMDespite all our efforts for an honorable peace in Vietnam, <strong>the</strong> warcontinues. I cannot predict when it will end. Thus our plans mustassume its long duration.But peace will return—and it could return sooner than we dare expect.When hostilities do end, we will be faced with a great opportunity,and a challenge how best to use that opportunity. The resources nowbeing claimed by <strong>the</strong> war can be diverted to peaceful uses both at homeand abroad, and can hasten <strong>the</strong> attainment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> great goals upon whichwe have set our sights.If we keep our eyes firmly fixed on those goals—and if we planwisely—we need have no fear that <strong>the</strong> bridge from war to peace willexact a wasteful toll <strong>of</strong> idle resources, human or material.But when that welcome day <strong>of</strong> peace arrives, we will need quick adjustmentsin our economic policies. We must be prepared for those23


adjustments, ready to act rapidly—both to avoid interruption to ourprosperity and to take full and immediate advantage <strong>of</strong> our opportunities.Planning for peace has been an important activity in many executiveagencies. But <strong>the</strong> effort needs to be stepped up and integrated.Accordingly, I am instructing <strong>the</strong> heads <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> relevant agencies in <strong>the</strong>Executive Branch, under <strong>the</strong> leadership <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Chairman <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Council<strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers, to begin at once a major and coordinated effortto review our readiness. I have asked <strong>the</strong>m—to consider possibilities and priorities for tax reduction;—to prepare, with <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve Board, plans for quickadjustments <strong>of</strong> monetary and financial policies;—to determine which high priority programs can be quicklyexpanded;—to determine priorities for <strong>the</strong> longer range expansion <strong>of</strong> programsto meet <strong>the</strong> needs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> American people, both throughnew and existing programs;—to study and evaluate <strong>the</strong> future direction <strong>of</strong> Federal financialsupport to our States and local governments;—to examine ways in which <strong>the</strong> transition to peace can be smoo<strong>the</strong>dfor <strong>the</strong> workers, companies, and communities now engaged insupplying our defense needs, and <strong>the</strong> men released from ourarmed forces.I have directed that initial reports be prepared on all <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se and relatedproblems, and that <strong>the</strong>reafter <strong>the</strong>y be kept continuously up to date.CONCLUSIONOur task for 1967 is to sustain fur<strong>the</strong>r sound and rewarding economicprogress while we move toward solutions for <strong>the</strong> problems we met in1966. It will require a flexible and delicate balance <strong>of</strong> economicpolicies.Above all, we must guard against any interruption <strong>of</strong> our prosperity.The steady advance <strong>of</strong> jobs and incomes is our most powerful weaponin <strong>the</strong> battle against poverty and discrimination at home. And it undergirdsour policy around <strong>the</strong> world.Yet we must be equally alert to <strong>the</strong> dangers <strong>of</strong> inflation.In his <strong>Economic</strong> <strong>Report</strong> <strong>of</strong> January 1956, <strong>President</strong> Eisenhower wrote:The continuance <strong>of</strong> general prosperity cannot be taken for granted.In a high-level economy like ours, nei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> threat <strong>of</strong> inflation nor<strong>the</strong> threat <strong>of</strong> recession can ever be very distant. . . . The only rigid24


ule we can afford to admit to our minds is <strong>the</strong> principle that <strong>the</strong> bestway to fight a recession is to try to prevent it from occurring.Only 18 months later, <strong>the</strong> sharpest recession <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> entire postwarperiod began—which also led to <strong>the</strong> largest peacetime budget deficit inour history. Over <strong>the</strong> same 18 months, both consumer prices and wholesaleprices advanced 5J/2 percent—considerably faster than in <strong>the</strong> 18months since June 1965.That history does not invalidate but ra<strong>the</strong>r reinforces <strong>President</strong> Eisenhower'sproposition. Nei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> threat <strong>of</strong> inflation nor <strong>of</strong> recession isever distant in a high level economy.How can we steer between <strong>the</strong>se dangers, and—at <strong>the</strong> same time—supply <strong>the</strong> needs <strong>of</strong> national defense, streng<strong>the</strong>n our overseas payments,relieve <strong>the</strong> inequities <strong>of</strong> tight money and high interest rates, maintain<strong>the</strong> momentum <strong>of</strong> social progress, and provide <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> incomeswhich lets each <strong>of</strong> us move toward fulfilling his private aspirations?I am confident that we can find such a course. We will continue tocoordinate <strong>the</strong> tools <strong>of</strong> monetary and fiscal policy to <strong>the</strong> common goal—<strong>the</strong> sound, balanced, and noninflationary advance <strong>of</strong> production and incomes.We are steering toward lower interest rates, a better balancein our economy, a budget and a Social Security program that reflectnational priorities.There will be surprises in store along <strong>the</strong> way. We must be preparedto meet <strong>the</strong>m swiftly and flexibly. And I think we are. The tools <strong>of</strong>economic policy are not perfect; but <strong>the</strong>y are far better understoodand accepted—in <strong>the</strong> Government and in <strong>the</strong> private community—thanever before.We have surely proved over recent years that economic progressdoes not need to be interrupted by frequent recessions. And, althoughprices have risen faster in <strong>the</strong> past year and a half than we expected orwished, we have done better than in most similar periods <strong>of</strong> our economichistory. And we have done it without burdensome controls on prices orwages.The Federal Government cannot do <strong>the</strong> whole job—or even verymuch <strong>of</strong> it. Production and incomes arise from <strong>the</strong> strength and skill<strong>of</strong> workers, <strong>the</strong> ingenuity <strong>of</strong> managements, <strong>the</strong> willingness <strong>of</strong> savers torisk <strong>the</strong>ir capital, <strong>the</strong> genius <strong>of</strong> inventors and engineers, <strong>the</strong> patience <strong>of</strong>teachers, <strong>the</strong> devotion <strong>of</strong> local public servants—<strong>the</strong> contributions <strong>of</strong> allwho participate in our economy.Yet <strong>the</strong> Federal Government has a role <strong>of</strong> leadership and a responsibilityfor coordination.25


The Congress defined that role in <strong>the</strong> Employment Act <strong>of</strong> 1946:... it is <strong>the</strong> continuing policy and responsibility <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> FederalGovernment . . .. . . with <strong>the</strong> assistance and cooperation <strong>of</strong> industry, agriculture,labor, and State and local governments,to coordinate and utilize all its plans, functions, and resources for<strong>the</strong> purpose <strong>of</strong> creating and maintaining,in a manner calculated to foster and promote free competitiveenterprise and <strong>the</strong> general welfare, . . .. . . useful employment opportunities . . . for those able, willingand seeking to work,and to promote maximum employment, production, and purchasingpower.Our economic policies for 1967 respond to that mandate.January 26, 1967.26


THE ANNUAL REPORTOF THECOUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS27


LETTER OF TRANSMITTALTHE PRESIDENT:COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS,Washington, D.C., January 19,1967.SIR: The Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers herewith submits its Annual<strong>Report</strong>, January 1967, in accordance with Section 4(c) (2) <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> EmploymentAct <strong>of</strong> 1946.Respectfully,GARDNER ACKLEY,Chairman.JAMES S.DUESENBERRYARTHUR M.OKUN240-782 O—6729


CONTENTSPageCHAPTER 1. EXTENDING THE RECORD OF PROSPERITY 37Achievements <strong>of</strong> an Expanding Economy 38Employment Gains 38Productivity 40Gains in Real Income 41The Realization <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Potential 42Strains and Restraint in a Surging Economy 45The Economy in Mid-1965 45Spurt in <strong>Economic</strong> Activity 46Moderation in <strong>the</strong> Pace <strong>of</strong> Advance 48Retrospect 49The Pattern <strong>of</strong> Output 50Uneven Shares in Investment 50Inventory Investment 52Money and Credit 52Promoting Expansion, 1961 to 1965 53Shift to Restraint 54Competition Among Financial Institutions 55Actions to Reduce Financial Pressures 58Signs <strong>of</strong> Relaxation 59Evaluation <strong>of</strong> Monetary Restraint 60Prospects and Policies for 1967 61Fiscal Program for 1967 61<strong>Economic</strong> Outlook 62Improving Stabilization Tools Over <strong>the</strong> Longer Run 65Uses <strong>of</strong> Monetary Policy 65Need for Fiscal Flexibility 68Appendix: The Federal Budget, National Income AccountsBasis 69CHAPTER 2. PRICES AND WAGES IN 1966 72The Recent Price Record 74Labor Compensation and Labor Costs 77Supply and Demand in <strong>the</strong> Labor Market 78Prices in Major Sectors 86Farm Products and Food 87Raw Materials 89Manufactured Goods 90Consumer Services 9331


CHAPTER 2. PRICES AND WAGES IN 1966—Continuedp ag ePrices and <strong>the</strong> Distribution <strong>of</strong> Real Income 95Outlook for Prices 97CHAPTER 3. MAINTAINING PRICE STABILITY AND REDUCING UNEM-PLOYMENT 99Improving U.S. Labor Markets 100Composition <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Unemployed 101"Frictional" Unemployment 104Improving <strong>the</strong> Operation <strong>of</strong> Labor Markets 106"Structural" Unemployment 107Federal Manpower Training 108Improving <strong>the</strong> Performance <strong>of</strong> Product Markets 113Streng<strong>the</strong>ning Competition 113Resale Price Maintenance 115Restrictions on International Trade 116Regulatory Policies 116Direct Government Actions Affecting Supply 117Wage-Price Policies 119The Council's Wage-Price Guideposts 120Government Activities to Promote Guidepost Adherence. . 125Basic Problems for Wage-Price Policy in 1967 127A Wage-Price Policy for 1967 128CHAPTER 4. SELECTED USES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 135Private and Public Goods 135Consumer Choice 136External Effects 136Income Maintenance 138Poverty and Work 138Income Maintenance and <strong>the</strong> Poor 139Toward Improved Income Maintenance for <strong>the</strong> Poor 142Social Security 142Education 143Value <strong>of</strong> Education 143Trends in Demand and Costs 146Health Care 149Demand for Medical Care 150Cost Factors 152Prospects for <strong>the</strong> Coming Decade 152Cities 153Elements <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Urban Problem 154Meeting <strong>the</strong> Cities' Problems 157Federal, State, and Local Fiscal Relations 161Taxation 161State and Local Fiscal Problem 162Categorical Federal Aid 16332


CHAPTER 4. SELECTED USES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH—Con.Federal, State, and Local Fiscal Relations—Continued PageGeneral Support Grants 165Credit for State Income Taxes 166Joint Revenue Collection 166O<strong>the</strong>r Issues <strong>of</strong> Tax Coordination 166Conclusion 167CHAPTER 5. GROWTH AND BALANCE IN THE WORLD ECONOMY 170World <strong>Economic</strong> Growth in <strong>the</strong> 1960's 170Developed Countries 171Less Developed Countries 172Trade Policies 175U.S. Balance <strong>of</strong> Payments 177Recent Developments 179Prospects and Policies for 1967 185Balance <strong>of</strong> Payments Adjustment Policies 187<strong>Report</strong> on <strong>the</strong> Adjustment Process 187U.S. Adjustment Policies 188Adjustment Policies <strong>of</strong> O<strong>the</strong>r Developed Countries 191International Monetary Reform 195APPENDIXES:A. <strong>Report</strong> to <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> on <strong>the</strong> Activities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Council <strong>of</strong><strong>Economic</strong> Advisers During 1966 199B. Statistical Tables Relating to Income, Employment, andProduction 207List <strong>of</strong> Tables and ChartsTables1. Changes in <strong>Economic</strong> Activity Since 1961 392. Changes in Measures <strong>of</strong> Income Since 1961 423. Changes in Gross National Product During Two Periods SinceMid-1965 474. Net Funds Raised by Domestic Nonfinancial Sectors, 1961-66. 535. Relation <strong>of</strong> Two Measures <strong>of</strong> Federal Budget Surplus or Deficit,Calendar Year 1966 706. Changes in Wholesale and Consumer Prices, 1964-66 757. Changes in Wholesale Prices, December 1965 to December 1966. 778. Changes in Consumer Prices, 1960-66 779. Changes in Employment, by Industry, 1960-66 7910. Wage Changes in Major Collective Bargaining Situations,1961-66 8111. Changes in Average Hourly Earnings, by Industry, 1960-66.... 8212. Changes in Compensation, Productivity, and Unit LaborCost in <strong>the</strong> Private Economy Since 1947 8313. Manufacturing Capacity Utilization, 1965-66 9114. Changes in Consumer Prices for Services During 1966 9433


Tables15. Changes in Consumer Prices for Typical Labor-intensive PageServices Since 1959 9516. Unemployment Rates, by Major Occupation Groups, 1961and 1966 10217. Unemployment, by Age, Sex, and Color, 1966 10218. Training Opportunities, Fiscal Years 1966-67 10919. The Poor and Their Work Experience, 1965 13920. Number <strong>of</strong> Poor Households and Incidence <strong>of</strong> Poverty, 1959,1962, and 1965 14021. Costs <strong>of</strong> Formal Education, 1966-67 14422. Earnings <strong>of</strong> Males, by Years <strong>of</strong> School Completed and O<strong>the</strong>rCharacteristics, 1959 14423. The Nation's Health Budget, 1965 14924. Physician and Dental Visits Per Year, by Age and FamilyIncome, 1963-64 15125. Characteristics <strong>of</strong> Population by Area 15526. Federal and State and Local Government Receipts, by Source,National Income and Product Accounts, 1965 16227. Federal and State and Local Government Expenditures, byMajor Function, National Income and Product Accounts,1965 16228. Growth <strong>of</strong> Federal Aid to State and Local Governments, FiscalYears 1930-68 16329. Changes in Total and Per Capita Real GNP in OECD and LessDeveloped Countries Since 1955 . 17130. United States Balance <strong>of</strong> Payments, 1960-66 18131. United States Balance <strong>of</strong> Payments: Capital Transactions,1960-66 .* 183Charts1. Gross National Product, Actual and Potential, and UnemploymentRate 432. Selected Shares <strong>of</strong> Gross National Product 513. Investment and Gross Saving <strong>of</strong> Nonfinancial Corporations.. . 544. Selected Interest Rates 565. Interest Rate Differentials and Household Security Purchases. 576. Wholesale Prices 757. Consumer Prices 768. Employment in Durable Goods Manufacturing 809. Unit Labor Costs in Manufacturing Since 1948 8610. Farm and Food Prices 8811. Shares <strong>of</strong> Gross Corporate Income 9712. Unemployment Rates 10313. Educational Attainment 14734


ChartsPage14. Age Adjusted Death Rates 15015. Municipal Expenditures, Per Capita 15716. U.S. Balance <strong>of</strong> International Payments 18017. Interest Rates in Selected Countries 19435


Chapter 1Extending <strong>the</strong> Record <strong>of</strong> ProsperityTHE UNITED STATES in 1966 enjoyed <strong>the</strong> benefits <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> fullest employmentin more than a decade. The unemployment rate reached a13-year low <strong>of</strong> 3.9 percent. At that level, demand finally matched supply inmost labor markets, a situation which economists define as essentially "fullemployment."Real incomes <strong>of</strong> all major groups registered sizable gains. Expansioncontinued for <strong>the</strong> sixth straight year. For <strong>the</strong> third successive year, grow<strong>the</strong>xceeded 5}4 percent, a record unparalleled in our postwar experience.By any standard, <strong>the</strong>n, 1966 was a big year for <strong>the</strong> economy. Gross nationalproduct (GNP) expanded by a record $58 billion in current pricesand reached $740 billion. As in <strong>the</strong> 2 preceding years, a major advance inbusiness fixed investment was a key expansionary force. And <strong>the</strong> risingrequirements <strong>of</strong> Vietnam ddded $10 billion to defense outlays. State andlocal spending and inventory investment also rose strongly.As a result, 1966 was in some respects too big a year, especially in <strong>the</strong> earlymonths. Spurred by <strong>the</strong> defense buildup, total demand—public andprivate— forged ahead at an extraordinarily rapid rate in late 1965 and early1966. Strains developed in financial markets. Demand outstripped supplyin several sectors which were already near full utilization. As Chapter 2explains, many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new orders simply added to backlogs and put upwardpressures on prices. Some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> excess demands were met by imports, reducing<strong>the</strong> U.S. foreign trade surplus and retarding progress toward equilibriumin <strong>the</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> payments, as Chapter 5 indicates.After years <strong>of</strong> stimulating demand, policy was called upon to restrain<strong>the</strong> economy. The need for restraint was recognized at <strong>the</strong> start <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>year. Monetary policy assumed a restrictive stance. In anticipation <strong>of</strong>large increases in private expenditures and defense outlays, tax policieswere applied to curb private demand. In 1964 and 1965, an expansionarytax policy had stimulated <strong>the</strong> economy; but in March 1966, restrictive taxchanges were enacted at <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong>'s request. Excise tax cuts werepostponed, and income tax payments were accelerated. Moreover, <strong>the</strong><strong>President</strong>'s budget program in January stringently held down nondefenseoutlays. These measures produced a Federal surplus in <strong>the</strong> national incomeaccounts budget and a net restrictive fiscal impact in <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong>1966, despite <strong>the</strong> strong advance in defense spending.37


But <strong>the</strong> magnitude <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> task was not fully appreciated at <strong>the</strong> beginning<strong>of</strong> 1966. As private demand and Vietnam requirements exceeded forecasts,policy was adjusted to <strong>the</strong> new developments. Monetary policy tightenedfur<strong>the</strong>r, causing a major cutback in homebuilding. In September, <strong>the</strong><strong>President</strong> proposed additional selective fiscal measures to alleviate excessivedemands for funds and for capital goods.The initial restraining measures, reinforced by <strong>the</strong> previously enacted risein payroll taxes, began to take effect in <strong>the</strong> spring. By <strong>the</strong> closing months <strong>of</strong>1966, it was clear that <strong>the</strong> brakes had worked. The economy had shouldered<strong>the</strong> burden <strong>of</strong> active hostilities without <strong>the</strong> need for cumbersome andinefficient controls and without losing its basic health and stability. It wasshown that policy could work both ways; it could restrain <strong>the</strong> economy, muchas it had been able to provide stimulus during <strong>the</strong> preceding 5 years. Inparticular, <strong>the</strong> power <strong>of</strong> tight money as a tool <strong>of</strong> restraint—as well as itsuneven impact—was demonstrated beyond any reasonable doubt.As 1967 opens, inflationary forces set in motion during <strong>the</strong> period <strong>of</strong>overly rapid expansion are still alive, although <strong>the</strong>ir strength is waning.But now <strong>the</strong>re is also a renewed challenge to sustain expansion; any fur<strong>the</strong>rslowdown would be undesirable.A healthy advance <strong>of</strong> demand in pace with <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> potential outputwould permit gradual restoration <strong>of</strong> price stability. It would also promotea recovery in our foreign trade balance, <strong>the</strong>reby aiding <strong>the</strong> pursuit<strong>of</strong> equilibrium in <strong>the</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> payments. The fiscal program for 1967is designed to meet <strong>the</strong>se objectives and to assure that <strong>the</strong> easing <strong>of</strong> monetaryconditions, presently underway, can be extended.ACHIEVEMENTS OF AN EXPANDING ECONOMYLast year's record <strong>of</strong> economic gains added in length and strength to <strong>the</strong>remarkable uninterrupted expansion that began early in 1961 (Table 1).This advance can be viewed in many dimensions. Prosperity has conferredits benefits on nearly every sector, industry, and region in almost every year.EMPLOYMENT GAINSOf all its facets, <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> employment may be <strong>of</strong> greatest significance.Increasing numbers <strong>of</strong> Americans have obtained opportunities to earnsecure livelihoods and to contribute to <strong>the</strong> material welfare <strong>of</strong> society.Employment in 1966Employment gains in 1966 were <strong>the</strong> largest <strong>of</strong> any year in <strong>the</strong> expansion.Civilian employment increased by 1.9 million, and 400,000 persons wereadded to <strong>the</strong> Armed Forces. The civilian unemployment rate fell from 4.6percent in 1965 to 3.9 percent in 1966, <strong>the</strong> lowest since 1953. During <strong>the</strong>year, <strong>the</strong> seasonally adjusted rate remained essentially on a plateau, fluctuatingbetween 3.7 and 4.0 percent. The number <strong>of</strong> persons unemployed38


TABLE 1.—Changes in economic activity since 1961Percentage change per yearMeasure <strong>of</strong> economic activity1961to19661961to19621962to19631963to19641964to19651965to19661Production:Gross national product, constant prices 2Personal consumption expendituresBusiness fixed investmentResidential structuresGovernment purchases <strong>of</strong> goods and services..Federal ._State and localIndustrial productionPrices: GNP deflator_5.45.29.74.23.35.27.31.86.64.99.210 27.09.93.57.81.14.04.44.44 22.0-.85.55.11.35.35.810.6—.81.6-2.96.66.41.65.96.013.1—2.02.5(3) 5.48.41.85.44.911.2-10.88.010.95.09.03.0Employment:Total civilian employmentNonagricultural payroll employment2.23.41.82.91.42.02.22.92.64.22.65.11 Preliminary.2 Includes change in business inventories and net exports <strong>of</strong> goods and services, not shown separately.3 Less than .05 percent.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal ReserveSystem, and Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers.dropped by 500,000 in 1966. Nearly all groups shared in <strong>the</strong> reduction,<strong>the</strong> only exceptions being nonwhite females in two age groups, 14-19 and 45years and over. Although employment in both <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se groups expanded,<strong>the</strong> increase was not enough to keep pace with <strong>the</strong> rapid growth <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>segroups in <strong>the</strong> labor force.The expansion in <strong>the</strong> demand for labor extended to every nonagriculturalsector <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy. The most remarkable gains were in manufacturingwhere <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> jobs rose 1 million from 1965 to 1966. Since mostmanufacturing employment consists <strong>of</strong>. high-productivity, high-wage jobs,<strong>the</strong> gain contributed to a major advance in real income. Employment intrade and services and State and local governments also expanded substantially,rising by about V/2 million workers in 1966.The mirror image <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rapid increase in nonagricultural jobs was a remarkabledecline <strong>of</strong> 400,000 in agricultural employment in 1966. Thisdecrease <strong>of</strong> 8J/4 percent was <strong>the</strong> largest percentage drop on record, as higherpayingnonfarm job opportunities attracted farmers and hired workers out<strong>of</strong> agriculture.Labor SupplyThe labor force expanded by 1.8 million workers last year, nearly 500,000more than demographic trends alone would have indicated. In particular,a larger fraction <strong>of</strong> women and teenagers participated in <strong>the</strong> labor force.Low unemployment encourages entry into <strong>the</strong> labor force. Some people,especially women and teenagers, who would be interested in working if jobswere plentiful, do not actively search for jobs when <strong>the</strong>y believe none areavailable. At such times, <strong>the</strong>se persons are considered nei<strong>the</strong>r as employed39


nor unemployed, and are not counted in <strong>the</strong> labor force. When job opportunitiesimprove, <strong>the</strong>y enter <strong>the</strong> labor force, seeking and frequently findingjobs. The evidence <strong>of</strong> 1966 suggests that nearly 500,000 <strong>of</strong> "hiddenunemployed" or "discouraged workers" entered <strong>the</strong> labor force. Probably,additional workers, who did not respond fully to improved job opportunitieslast year, will enter <strong>the</strong> labor market if it remains buoyant.The Record Since 1961The number <strong>of</strong> unemployed today is about 2 million lower than 6 yearsago. Over <strong>the</strong> same period, nearly 9 million additional Americans havegained employment. Millions more moved into higher paying, more secure,and better jobs, and out <strong>of</strong> declining areas and low-wage industries. Thebenefits <strong>of</strong> full employment have extended far beyond <strong>the</strong> important gainsin real income and material welfare. By reducing poverty and hardship, <strong>the</strong>opportunities for productive employment have contributed to human dignityand self-esteem and to freedom <strong>of</strong> choice.The decline in unemployment in a vigorous and buoyant economy haschanged <strong>the</strong> diagnoses and <strong>the</strong> proposed remedies for our labor market problems.Allegations that a substantial fraction <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> labor force lacks <strong>the</strong>motivation to work have been refuted by <strong>the</strong> facts. Proposals to cut unemploymentby artificially shortening <strong>the</strong> workweek, or by instituting practicesdeliberately designed to hold down productivity, are no longer seriouslyadvanced.The marked decline in unemployment in <strong>the</strong> past 6 years has been sharedby nearly all groups. In some instances, improvement has been dramatic.Only one-third as many Americans were unemployed for 15 consecutiveweeks or longer in 1966 as in 1961. Over <strong>the</strong> same period, <strong>the</strong> unemploymentrates for nonwhite adult males, blue collar workers, and married menfell by more than half.Many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> previously hard core depressed areas are no longer sufferingfrom high unemployment. In early 1961, 101 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Nation's 150 majorlabor market areas were classified as areas <strong>of</strong> substantial unemployment, withrates in excess <strong>of</strong> 6 percent. Today, <strong>the</strong>re are only 8 labor market areas inthat category. There are now 66 areas that have unemployment rates <strong>of</strong> lessthan 3 percent; for most <strong>of</strong> 1961, <strong>the</strong>re were none.Of course, some groups have gained less than o<strong>the</strong>rs. Unemploymentremains high among nonwhites, teenagers, and, especially among workerswith few skills and little training. As Chapter 3 indicates, inexperience,inadequate education, and racial discrimination unfortunately penalize <strong>the</strong>segroups, placing <strong>the</strong>ir members at <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> all too many hiring lines.PRODUCTIVITYProductivity increases during <strong>the</strong> expansion have been excellent. Theslow growth in <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> adult male workers was <strong>of</strong>ten cited as a reasonfor expecting bottlenecks in <strong>the</strong> labor market and a sluggish productivity40


performance during <strong>the</strong> expansion. However, from 1961 to 1966, <strong>the</strong> averageannual growth <strong>of</strong> private output per man-hour was 3.5 percent, exceeding<strong>the</strong> long-term trend <strong>of</strong> a little over 3 percent a year.One factor making for good productivity performance in recent years hasbeen <strong>the</strong> high level <strong>of</strong> business investment expenditures. As a result, capitalhas not been a bottleneck to <strong>the</strong> expansion <strong>of</strong> production and employmentin most areas and industries. Moreover, high investment rates have helpedto modernize <strong>the</strong> capital stock and <strong>the</strong>reby speed technological progress.In large part, however, <strong>the</strong> above-normal growth <strong>of</strong> productivity is typical<strong>of</strong> economic recoveries. A slack economy does not make full use <strong>of</strong> itscapital stock or overhead labor. As activity expands, both are utilized moreefficiently and productivity increases. But this cannot go on indefinitely.In 1965 and 1966, average use <strong>of</strong> plant and equipment approached "preferred"rates, and overhead labor had to be expanded. As a result <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>sefactors and need for major, rapid adjustments in <strong>the</strong> composition <strong>of</strong>employment, growth <strong>of</strong> productivity slowed in 1965 and 1966 to just under3 percent, slightly below <strong>the</strong> long-term trend.GAINS IN REAL INCOMEAdvances in employment and productivity have generated unprecedentedgains in <strong>the</strong> real income and <strong>the</strong> standard <strong>of</strong> living <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> American people.Farmers, wage earners, businessmen, and pr<strong>of</strong>essional workers have allshared in <strong>the</strong> impressive advance. Real disposable income per capita—<strong>the</strong>best single measure <strong>of</strong> consumer welfare—has risen by 24 percent over <strong>the</strong>past 6 years, matching <strong>the</strong> increase in <strong>the</strong> preceding 13 years.Gains have been particularly rapid in recent years. In 1964 and 1965,real disposable income per capita increased by 5 percent a year—<strong>the</strong> equivalent<strong>of</strong> more than 2 extra weekly paychecks annually. Despite <strong>the</strong> disturbingrise in consumer prices in 1966, real disposable income per capita continuedto grow strongly—by Z l /i percent. The higher incomes <strong>of</strong> 1966included a 12 percent increase in social insurance transfer payments,which aided some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> needier groups.Since 1961, <strong>the</strong>re have been impressive advances in each type <strong>of</strong> incomeas well as in total income, as shown in Table 2. Through 1965, <strong>the</strong>growth <strong>of</strong> corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its outpaced GNP and most o<strong>the</strong>r types <strong>of</strong> income.In 1966, however, pr<strong>of</strong>its rose in line with GNP and less rapidly than employeecompensation.The full story <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> welfare gains from economic expansion cannot beconveyed by any array <strong>of</strong> statistics. O<strong>the</strong>r data—such as <strong>the</strong> rapid growthin <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> families owning durable goods and <strong>the</strong> greater percentage<strong>of</strong> families enjoying adequate diets and medical facilities—could be presentedto document various trends. But <strong>the</strong>y all add up to <strong>the</strong> single story


TABLE 2.—Changes in measures <strong>of</strong> income since 1961Measure <strong>of</strong> income1961 1965 19661Billions <strong>of</strong> dollarsPercentage changeper year»1961to19661965to1966Compensation <strong>of</strong> employeesCorporate pr<strong>of</strong>its:Before taxes..After taxes302.650.327.2392.975.744.5433.381.848.17.410.212.110.38.18.1Disposable personal income:Current prices1958 pricesFarm income per farm:Current prices1966prices364.4350.73,3893,684469.1430.8Dollars4,4934,632505.3451.54,9554,9556.85.27.96.17.74.810.37.0» Preliminary.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, and Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers.that sustained prosperity means more comfort, more freedom, and moresecurity for <strong>the</strong> overwhelming majority <strong>of</strong> Americans.THE REALIZATION OF ECONOMIC POTENTIALA major economic accomplishment <strong>of</strong> 1966 is that <strong>the</strong> United States madeessentially full use <strong>of</strong> its productive potential. Gone were <strong>the</strong> chronic underutilization<strong>of</strong> resources, general excess supply in labor markets, and wastefullyidle industrial capacity that had blemished <strong>the</strong> performance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economyfor a decade. Because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> excessive unemployment and idle capital inprevious years, <strong>the</strong> Nation sacrificed <strong>the</strong> opportunity to consume and invest alarge amount <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> output that it was capable <strong>of</strong> producing. At <strong>the</strong> trough<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> recession in <strong>the</strong> first quarter <strong>of</strong> 1961, <strong>the</strong> "gap" between actual andpotential GNP amounted to $57 billion (1966 prices). From 1958 to 1965,<strong>the</strong> cumulative gap totaled $260 billion (Chart 1).Five years ago, when unemployment was 6 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> labor force, <strong>the</strong>rewas clearly an excess supply <strong>of</strong> labor. Nobody could be sure where balancebetween supply and demand would be reached. The Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong>Advisers, among o<strong>the</strong>rs, judged that an unemployment rate near 4 percentwould (with <strong>the</strong> existing structure <strong>of</strong> labor markets) yield approximate balancebetween <strong>the</strong> supply and demand for labor. O<strong>the</strong>r experts argued,however, that <strong>the</strong> economy would run into substantial and significant laborbottlenecks when unemployment fell to 5 percent. Ano<strong>the</strong>r group contendedoptimistically that a sufficient expansion <strong>of</strong> aggregate demand mightpush unemployment down as low as 3 percent without creating excess demandpressures. The experience <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> past year provides a partial answer,suggesting that <strong>the</strong> 4 percent judgment was nearest to <strong>the</strong> mark. In 1966,42


Chart 1Gross National Product, Actual and Potential,and Unemployment RateBILLIONS OF DOLLARS* (ratio scale)700650GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCTIN 1958 PRICES600550500POTENTIAL-*/\FACTUAL*450400I I I I 1 1 I I I I1956 1958 I960 1962 1964 1966PERCENTPERCENT• 6NP GAP AS PERCENT OF POTENTIAL (Left scab)•—• UNEMPLOYMENT RATE-2/(Right scab)126^rffc\0-61956 1958 1960 1962 19641966•SEASONALLY ADJUSTED ANNUAL RATES.J/TREND LINE OF y/i% THROUGH MIDDLE OF 1955 TO 1962 IV, 3%% FROM 1962 IV TO 1965 IV, AND 4%*FROM 1965 IV TO 1966 IV.^UNEMPLOYMENT AS PERCENT OF CIVILIAN LABOR FORCE; SEASONALLY ADJUSTED.SOURCES: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE, DEPARTMENT OF LABOR, AND COUNCIL OF ECONOMICADVISERS.43


labor markets were generally in balance, although <strong>the</strong>re were shortages <strong>of</strong>certain labor skills and a few remaining pockets <strong>of</strong> unemployment. Theareas <strong>of</strong> shortages seemed largely to reflect <strong>the</strong> speed <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy'sadvance ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> utilization attained. With <strong>the</strong> return <strong>of</strong>a more moderate advance, those pressures have begun to subside.The economy caught up with its economic potential in 1966. But totaldemand must continue to rise to keep pace with a growing potential GNP.Indeed, primarily as a result <strong>of</strong> faster growth <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> labor force, potentialoutput itself has been accelerating somewhat. From <strong>the</strong> mid-1950's into<strong>the</strong> early 1960's, it advanced by about 3 J/2 percent a year. More recently,<strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> growth moved up to 3% percent a year; and at present, it seemsto be advancing at an annual rate <strong>of</strong> about 4 percent.The growth <strong>of</strong> potential stems from three principal determinants: <strong>the</strong>rise in <strong>the</strong> labor force; changes in annual average hours worked per man;and <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> average output per man-hour—that is, <strong>of</strong> productivity.Because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> low birth rates during <strong>the</strong> depression <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1930's and WorldWar II, <strong>the</strong> working-age population expanded slowly in <strong>the</strong> 1950's. However,high postwar birth rates have recently led to accelerated growth <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> labor force from 1*4 percent annually in earlier years to 1 ^4 percent.Under steady full employment conditions, longer vacations and shorterworkweeks would lead to an annual decline <strong>of</strong> about *4 percent in hoursworked per man, <strong>the</strong>reby reducing <strong>the</strong> growth in total man-hours to about15/2 percent a year.Labor productivity in <strong>the</strong> private economy has grown at a trend ratesomewhat over 3 percent a year during <strong>the</strong> postwar period. But, since <strong>the</strong>method <strong>of</strong> measuring productivity <strong>of</strong> Government workers ignores anychange in <strong>the</strong>ir efficiency, <strong>the</strong> trend rate <strong>of</strong> increase in output per man-hourin <strong>the</strong> total economy is just over 2}4 percent a year. Thus, with GNP perman-hour advancing at that rate and total man-hours at about 1 Y /i percent,potential output advances at 4 percent.The Nation's economic potential may grow even more rapidly in <strong>the</strong>future if <strong>the</strong> trend advance <strong>of</strong> productivity quickens. Two recent developments,in particular, could speed <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> productivity. First, <strong>the</strong>current investment boom has led to a significant modernization <strong>of</strong> ourcapital stock. About one-third <strong>of</strong> manufacturing equipment in use todayis less than 3 years old, compared with one-fourth at <strong>the</strong> beginning <strong>of</strong> 1964.When much <strong>of</strong> our capital stock is new, <strong>the</strong> production process will incorporatemany <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> latest technological advances. However, new investmentdoes not confer its productivity benefits immediately. Projects must firstbe completed and, even <strong>the</strong>n, <strong>the</strong>re are important start-up and break-incosts until new plant and equipment work smoothly. Hence, much <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>productivity bonus <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> recent capital boom may still lie ahead. Second,<strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> active manpower policies can make a significant contribution to<strong>the</strong> improvement <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> quality <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> labor force, and thus to productivity.44


Manpower policies may also increase growth rates over <strong>the</strong> long run bylowering <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> unemployment consistent with price stability. In fact,significant fur<strong>the</strong>r reductions in unemployment will depend primarily onmanpower programs, particularly those aimed at disadvantaged groups, asdiscussed in Chapter 3.The closing <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> gap in 1966 was a great achievement. But it necessarilymeans that <strong>the</strong> 5J/2 percent rate <strong>of</strong> advance <strong>of</strong> real output registered in recentyears cannot be matched in <strong>the</strong> near future. That rapid expansion waspossible because idle resources were ready and able to make a productivecontribution. The growth <strong>of</strong> employment outpaced <strong>the</strong> expansion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>civilian labor force; many new employees were put to work on previouslyidle or underused machines; improved utilization rates yielded a bonus <strong>of</strong>extra gains in productivity. But now that full employment has beenessentially attained, output cannot continue to rise faster than productivecapacity.STRAINS AND RESTRAINT IN A SURGING ECONOMYThe major <strong>the</strong>me <strong>of</strong> recent economic developments is <strong>the</strong> continuation<strong>of</strong> progress. But <strong>the</strong>re is also a secondary <strong>the</strong>me <strong>of</strong> problems and imbalances,many <strong>of</strong> which can be traced back to mid-1965, when <strong>the</strong> sudden increasein defense requirements for Vietnam led to a marked acceleration in economicactivity. By <strong>the</strong> time measures <strong>of</strong> fiscal and monetary restraint tookhold and slowed down <strong>the</strong> economy, significant problems had developed—aninterruption <strong>of</strong> price stability, a deterioration in international trade performance,acute pressures in financial markets, and sharply divergent movementsamong <strong>the</strong> various sectors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy.THE ECONOMY IN MID-1965As <strong>of</strong> mid-1965, <strong>the</strong> economy was advancing steadily and healthily towardfull employment. GNP had risen by $11 billion a quarter, on <strong>the</strong> average,for <strong>the</strong> preceding 2 years; <strong>the</strong> annual rate <strong>of</strong> real growth over that periodhad been 5}4 percent. Unemployment was down to 4^2 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>civilian labor force, and <strong>the</strong> average operating rate <strong>of</strong> manufacturing capacitywas up to 89 percent. The price record showed few blemishes: averageconsumer prices in July 1965 were only 6 percent higher than <strong>the</strong>y had beenin early 1961, and prices <strong>of</strong> nonfood commodities had risen by only 3 percent.Prices <strong>of</strong> manufactured finished products at wholesale had advanced by1 percent in 5 years.Expansionary fiscal policy had contributed actively to <strong>the</strong> record <strong>of</strong> 52months <strong>of</strong> advance. The reform <strong>of</strong> depreciation rules and <strong>the</strong> investmenttax credit, both initiated in 1962, encouraged business to expand andmodernize plant and equipment. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, as a result <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se measuresand <strong>the</strong> much larger tax reductions granted by <strong>the</strong> Revenue Act <strong>of</strong>240-782 0—67- 45


1964, both corporate and individual income recipients were enjoying anaverage reduction <strong>of</strong> one-fifth in <strong>the</strong>ir tax liabilities. Monetary policy continuedto meet <strong>the</strong> credit needs <strong>of</strong> a brisk expansion and <strong>the</strong>reby contributedto <strong>the</strong> relative stability <strong>of</strong> long-term interest rates that was unusual for aperiod <strong>of</strong> rapid economic advance. Meanwhile, Federal spending on goodsand services was essentially level after mid-1962. As a share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> growingGNP, defense purchases fell steadily from 9.2 percent in 1962 to a post-Korean low <strong>of</strong> 7.3 percent by mid-1965. Defense spending was clearlynot <strong>the</strong> fuel that was propelling <strong>the</strong> economy toward full employment. Butnei<strong>the</strong>r was <strong>the</strong> decline in <strong>the</strong> defense share permitted to retard <strong>the</strong> growth<strong>of</strong> total demand; some economic stimulus was provided by spending on newFederal civilian programs, and major reductions in taxes encouraged privatespending.New stimulative policies were being prepared in <strong>the</strong> spring <strong>of</strong> 1965 tocomplete <strong>the</strong> advance to full employment. Congress enacted a major phasedreduction <strong>of</strong> excise taxes, in line with <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong>'s proposals, and its firststage took effect in June 1965, cutting taxes by $1% billion (annual rate).A liberalization <strong>of</strong> social insurance benefits, designed to help <strong>the</strong> aged, wasenacted to take effect retroactively. The larger benefits were to be financedby a payroll tax increase at <strong>the</strong> beginning <strong>of</strong> 1966. Meanwhile, <strong>the</strong> liberalization<strong>of</strong> benefits was expected to give <strong>the</strong> economy a significant stimulus in<strong>the</strong> fall <strong>of</strong> 1965 when an anticipated liquidation <strong>of</strong> steel inventories mighto<strong>the</strong>rwise have threatened a slowdown. The retroactive portion, which wasdisbursed in September, amounted to $900 million. Thereafter, annualbenefits were raised by about $2 billion.SPURT IN ECONOMIC ACTIVITYThe economic environment was significantly changed by <strong>the</strong> expansion<strong>of</strong> defense requirements. On July 28, 1965, <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> requested additionalfunds for defense and indicated that fur<strong>the</strong>r increases would berequired in January. Military outlays, at an annual rate, rose by nearly$2 billion a quarter in late 1965 and early 1966 (Table 3). Defense ordersexpanded very rapidly, spurring demands for labor and inventories bycontractors.Yet <strong>the</strong> defense buildup itself was not enough to account directly for <strong>the</strong>acceleration in <strong>the</strong> over-all economic advance. Ra<strong>the</strong>r, it reinforced <strong>the</strong>previously planned fiscal stimuli and <strong>the</strong> forward momentum <strong>of</strong> a strongeconomy close to full employment. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> expansion <strong>of</strong> defensespending contributed to a significant change in <strong>the</strong> climate <strong>of</strong> opinion.The Vietnam buildup virtually assured American businessmen that no economicreverse would occur in <strong>the</strong> near future. The impact on businessattitudes was intensified by unwarranted fears that <strong>the</strong> Vietnam conflictmight have consequences like those <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Korean conflict: direct controls,excess pr<strong>of</strong>its taxes, and a huge jump in prices <strong>of</strong> raw materials.4e


TABLE 3.—Changes in gross national product during two periods since mid-1965[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars, seasonally adjusted annual rates]Expenditure category1965 IIto1966 IChange1966 Ito1966 IV iGross national product _ _.Personal consumption expendituresDurable goodsNondurable goods _ __.Services_Gross private domestic investmentFixed investmentBusiness fixedinvestment 2Residential structuresChange in business inventories..Net exports <strong>of</strong> goods and servicesGovernment purchases <strong>of</strong> goods and servicesFederal.National defense.. _ _O<strong>the</strong>r_State and local. _1 Preliminary.2 Nonresidential structures and producers' durable equipment.NOTE.—Detail will not necessarily add to total because <strong>of</strong> rounding.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce and Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers,___.48.328.85.912.510.410.89.69.1.51.3-2.210.76.35.5.94.437.918.8-.26.812.23.5-2.04.7-6.75.5-1.216.910.610.9-.46.3The increase in defense spending swelled an already strongly risingtide <strong>of</strong> business investment expenditures. From <strong>the</strong> second quarter <strong>of</strong> 1965to <strong>the</strong> first quarter <strong>of</strong> 1966, business spending for new structures and equipmentrose by $9 billion. Defense, investment, and social security liberalization,in combination, speeded <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> disposable income. Consumerspending responded strongly, growing by $29 billion over this three-quarterinterval. All in all, GNP advanced at an average <strong>of</strong> $16 billion a quarter.Real output grew at a phenomenal annual rate <strong>of</strong> 7.2 percent, and industrialproduction rose at an annual rate <strong>of</strong> 9.7 percent.Unemployment fell from 4.7 percent to 3.8 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> civilian laborforce during this period. New orders for durable manufactured goods rosemarkedly (12 percent), with orders for electrical machinery (20 percent)and defense products (19 percent) increasing especially rapidly.The surge in demand for goods and labor created pressures on pricesin many areas. From October 1965 to July 1966, <strong>the</strong> annual rate <strong>of</strong> advancefor industrial wholesale prices stepped-up to 3 percent. Prices <strong>of</strong>industrial crude materials moved sharply upward—at an annual rate <strong>of</strong> 8percent from October to April. At <strong>the</strong> consumer level, demand pressuresraised prices <strong>of</strong> services and nonfood commodities and combined with specialsupply factors in agriculture to push up food prices. These price movementsand <strong>the</strong>ir consequences are discussed in detail in Chapter 2. All inall, <strong>the</strong> economy exceeded reasonable speed limits in <strong>the</strong> period from mid-1965 through <strong>the</strong> first quarter <strong>of</strong> 1966.47


MODERATION IN THE PACE OF ADVANCEAfter years <strong>of</strong> providing stimulus to <strong>the</strong> economy, policy changed directionat <strong>the</strong> turn <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year. Monetary policy accounted for a major share<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> restraint during most <strong>of</strong> 1966. As described in detail below, <strong>the</strong>{Federal Reserve restrained <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> credit supply in <strong>the</strong> face <strong>of</strong> extremelystrong demands for borrowing by business. With intense competitionfor funds, interest rates rose sharply. Institutions which supply mortgagefunds to <strong>the</strong> homebuilding industry lost deposits both to <strong>the</strong> commercialbanks and to <strong>the</strong> market for new corporate securities. As a result,residential construction was starved for funds, and <strong>the</strong> sharp decline in thissector was one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> principal moderating influences during <strong>the</strong> secondhalf <strong>of</strong> 1966.Fiscal policy also responded effectively. Although <strong>the</strong> special defense costsnecessarily swelled Federal outlays and were highly stimulative, restrictiveactions were taken in o<strong>the</strong>r areas. Increases in nondefense purchaseswere held to $300 million from 1965 to 1966. Several restrictive tax measureswere proposed in January 1966, and were enacted in mid-March. Theseincluded a reinstatement <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> earlier excise tax reduction, restoringabout $1 billion to <strong>the</strong> annual rate <strong>of</strong> Federal revenues; and a system <strong>of</strong> graduatedwithholding for individual income taxes that drew <strong>of</strong>f $1J4 billion (annualrate) from disposable income beginning in May. These new measuresfollowed <strong>the</strong> $6 billion increase in payroll taxes that took effect at <strong>the</strong> start <strong>of</strong>1966. In addition, revenues were increased in <strong>the</strong> spring by unusually largepayments on 1965 income tax liabilities.The national income accounts budget for <strong>the</strong> Federal sector shifted froma deficit at an annual rate <strong>of</strong> $1^2 billion in <strong>the</strong> second half <strong>of</strong> 1965 to asurplus at an annual rate <strong>of</strong> $3 billion in <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong> 1966. (As explainedin <strong>the</strong> Appendix to this Chapter, Federal fiscal policy is discussed throughoutthis <strong>Report</strong> in terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> national income accounts budget.)These monetary and fiscal actions helped to bring <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> over-alleconomic expansion in line with <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> capacity. After <strong>the</strong> firstquarter <strong>of</strong> 1966, gains in GNP slowed to an average <strong>of</strong> $12^2 billion aquarter, no longer outstripping <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> potential GNP. The unemploymentrate leveled <strong>of</strong>f, as employment gains essentially matched <strong>the</strong>growth <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> labor force. Manufacturing output actually rose less than<strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> manufacturing capacity, and average operating rates at yearendwere below <strong>the</strong> 91 percent that had been reached in <strong>the</strong> first quarter.The change <strong>of</strong> pace was first clearly noticeable in <strong>the</strong> spring. Fiscalrestraint appreciably slowed <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> disposable income in <strong>the</strong> secondquarter and contributed to a marked slowdown in consumer spending.During <strong>the</strong> summer, consumer demand perked up again. But homebuilding,which had declined moderately in <strong>the</strong> second quarter, was hit hard by<strong>the</strong> shortage <strong>of</strong> mortgage financing and took a sharp plunge, holding down<strong>the</strong> increase in economic activity.4s


Business demand for capital goods, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, continued to expandrapidly during <strong>the</strong> spring and summer. Although tight money, risingcosts <strong>of</strong> machinery and construction, declining prices <strong>of</strong> common stock, andappeals for voluntary restraint had moderating effects in particular firmsand industries, total business investment forged ahead. In August, both<strong>the</strong> Commerce-SEC anticipations survey and <strong>the</strong> National Industrial ConferenceBoard appropriations survey confirmed <strong>the</strong> vigor <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> capital boom.Commercial construction was <strong>the</strong> only type <strong>of</strong> business investment thatshowed weakness; it was restrained by <strong>the</strong> shortage <strong>of</strong> mortgage funds.The capital boom, in fact, was proving too vigorous. In view <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>growing backlogs <strong>of</strong> orders, shortages <strong>of</strong> certain types <strong>of</strong> skilled labor, risingprices in capital goods industries, and acute pressures <strong>of</strong> business credit demandson financial markets, <strong>the</strong>re was a clear need to moderate investmentdemand. On September 8, <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> asked Congress to suspend,until January 1, 1968, <strong>the</strong> 7 percent tax credit on investment in machineryand equipment and accelerated depreciation provisions on new buildings.At <strong>the</strong> same time, he initiated a program to reduce nondefensespending.The Commerce-SEC survey in November showed that only moderatefur<strong>the</strong>r increases in plant and equipment spending were planned through<strong>the</strong> second quarter <strong>of</strong> 1967. It also revealed that <strong>the</strong> actual increase incapital outlays in <strong>the</strong> third quarter was somewhat smaller than <strong>the</strong> plannedadvance reported in August; this was <strong>the</strong> first downward revision <strong>of</strong> plansin 3 years. The results <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> survey no doubt reflected several factors, including<strong>the</strong> moderation <strong>of</strong> economic expansion, <strong>the</strong> financial pressures onbusiness, and <strong>the</strong> suspension <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> investment tax incentives. Even thoughorders for machinery and equipment continued to outrun shipments throughDecember, <strong>the</strong>re were favorable prospects that <strong>the</strong> pressures <strong>of</strong> excess demandon capital goods industries would be lessened in <strong>the</strong> months ahead.RETROSPECTDespite <strong>the</strong> moderation after <strong>the</strong> first quarter, expansion for 1966 wasmore rapid than virtually anyone expected at <strong>the</strong> outset. At <strong>the</strong> time itwas presented last January, <strong>the</strong> Council's forecast that GNP in 1966 wouldrise strongly by $46^4 billion was somewhat above <strong>the</strong> typical forecast <strong>of</strong>private economists. Yet it turned out to be $12 billion too low. In part, <strong>the</strong>underestimate reflected <strong>the</strong> difference between <strong>the</strong> predicted real growth<strong>of</strong> nearly 5 percent and <strong>the</strong> actual rate <strong>of</strong> 5*4 percent. In addition, <strong>the</strong>over-all price deflator rose by 3 percent—about 1 percentage point morethan projected.The primary sources <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> underestimate were in Federal defense purchasesand business fixed investment. While both had been expected tobe key sources <strong>of</strong> strength, <strong>the</strong>y were even stronger than anticipated. As<strong>the</strong> prospective duration <strong>of</strong> Vietnam hostilities and <strong>the</strong> intensity <strong>of</strong> our militarycommitment exceeded those assumed in <strong>the</strong> budget, Federal spending49


for defense in <strong>the</strong> calendar year ran above last January's estimate by $4billion. Spurred in part by defense outlays, expenditures on plant andequipment topped <strong>the</strong> Council's expectations by $2 billion to $3 billion. Stateand local purchases and inventory investment also were above <strong>the</strong> projections,while homebuilding and net exports fell below <strong>the</strong> estimates.As it became clear that public and private demand was exceedingexpectations, <strong>the</strong> desirability <strong>of</strong> fur<strong>the</strong>r increases in taxes came under publicdiscussion. Continuing and careful consideration <strong>of</strong> this issue within <strong>the</strong>Administration, sharpened by <strong>the</strong> increasing strain on financial markets, ledto <strong>the</strong> fiscal program <strong>of</strong> September 8. In retrospect it is clear that, afterMarch, monetary and fiscal policy in combination provided adequate totalrestraint. It may be debated whe<strong>the</strong>r a better balance <strong>of</strong> demands andpolicies would have been achieved if a program <strong>of</strong> additional fiscal restrainthad been undertaken earlier in order to relieve <strong>the</strong> pressure on monetarypolicy. It may also be argued that <strong>the</strong> capital boom could have been cooled<strong>of</strong>f sooner if <strong>the</strong> investment tax credit had been suspended earlier in <strong>the</strong>year. The question <strong>of</strong> whe<strong>the</strong>r a different timing or different magnitude<strong>of</strong> fiscal actions might have produced a more favorable balance in 1966 willlong interest and challenge analysts <strong>of</strong> economic policy. But <strong>the</strong> main lessonis clear from <strong>the</strong> record: economic policy was used effectively to restrain<strong>the</strong> economy during 1966, much as it had been used during <strong>the</strong> preceding5 years to stimulate demand.THE PATTERN OF OUTPUTIn contrast to <strong>the</strong> reassuring balance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> expansion from 1961 to 1965,<strong>the</strong> advance in 1966 was uncomfortably uneven among sectors. The nature<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se imbalances is illustrated by Chart 2, which shows <strong>the</strong> shares <strong>of</strong>GNP absorbed by various types <strong>of</strong> expenditures since 1954.It is striking that <strong>the</strong> portion <strong>of</strong> GNP devoted to Federal purchases in1966 was much <strong>the</strong> same as in earlier years. Indeed, despite <strong>the</strong> sharpgrowth <strong>of</strong> defense outlays, Federal expenditures represented a smaller share<strong>of</strong> national product than in any o<strong>the</strong>r post-Korean year except 1964 and1965. The share <strong>of</strong> defense purchases was 8.1 percent, also lower than inany year from 1954 to 1963. State and local government purchases continued<strong>the</strong>ir secular rise as a share <strong>of</strong> GNP.The share <strong>of</strong> private domestic and foreign investment in 1966, 16 percent<strong>of</strong> GNP, was quite typical for a full-employment year. Private investmentexceeded private saving at full employment, leaving room for moderatesurpluses in government budgets (national income accounts basis).UNEVEN SHARES IN INVESTMENTAlthough <strong>the</strong> share <strong>of</strong> investment in GNP was normal, <strong>the</strong> pattern <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>major investment components was unusual when compared with o<strong>the</strong>r post-50


Chart 2Selected Shares <strong>of</strong> Gross National ProductPERCENT OFGNPDOMESTIC INVESTMENTGOVERNMENT PURCHASESAND NET EXPORTS1412BUSINESS FIXEDINVESTMENTXFEDERAL PURCHASESSTATE AND LOCALPURCHASESRESIDENTIAL STRUCTURESCHANGE INBUSINESSINVENTORIESNET EXPORTS-21954 56 58 60 62 64SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE.I I I I66 1954 56 58 60 62 64 66Korean years. Business fixed investment was at a record high <strong>of</strong> 10.7 percent<strong>of</strong> GNP, surpassing its previous peak <strong>of</strong> 10.5 percent in 1957 and considerablyabove its post-Korean average <strong>of</strong> 9.8 percent. Because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>scarcity <strong>of</strong> mortgage funds, housing starts fell steadily from an average <strong>of</strong>1.5 million units in <strong>the</strong> first quarter <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year to 1.0 million in <strong>the</strong> fourth;at 3.5 percent, <strong>the</strong> share <strong>of</strong> residential construction was at a post-Korean low.Inventory investment, at 1.5 percent, matched its previous post-Korean high<strong>of</strong> 1955. Excess demand at home generated a spurt in demand for goodsfrom abroad, pulling down <strong>the</strong> share <strong>of</strong> net exports to <strong>the</strong> lowest level since1959.


The record share <strong>of</strong> business fixed investment in 1966 occurred despite <strong>the</strong>need for a much greater volume <strong>of</strong> external financing at unusually highborrowing costs. Incentives to invest were provided by a continuation <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> forces that had spurred business to expand and modernize facilities in1964 and 1965: growing sales, orders, and pr<strong>of</strong>its, and high operating rates.These were fur<strong>the</strong>r streng<strong>the</strong>ned by <strong>the</strong> rise in defense spending.INVENTORY INVESTMENTA high rate <strong>of</strong> inventory investment in relation to GNP during 1966 reflectedmany <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> same factors that stimulated business fixed investment.Inventory-sales ratios generally crept up after years <strong>of</strong> stability or decline.Nonfarm stocks expanded by 8 percent over <strong>the</strong> year, considerably above<strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> real output or sales. Inventories rose especiallyrapidly in durable goods manufacturing; <strong>the</strong>se stocks grew by nearly $7 billionduring <strong>the</strong> first 11 months <strong>of</strong> 1966. Within durables, goods-in-processinventories rose by about $4 billion over <strong>the</strong> period, reflecting, in part, <strong>the</strong>build-up <strong>of</strong> defense and business equipment in <strong>the</strong> pipeline.The long production times that are essential for many durable goods werelargely responsible for <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> stocks <strong>of</strong> goods-in-process. From <strong>the</strong>time a company begins to build an airplane or a machine, it may take 6months or a year to produce a finished good and complete a shipment.While <strong>the</strong> piece <strong>of</strong> equipment is being fabricated, <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> completedportion shows up in inventories <strong>of</strong> goods-in-process. Thus, if orders risesharply for items with long production times, inventories grow; <strong>the</strong> ratio<strong>of</strong> inventories to shipments also tends to increase until shipments can catchup.In late 1965 and in 1966, orders for business equipment and defense hardgoodsrose sharply, and shipments did not keep pace. The economic impact<strong>of</strong> this step-up in orders was not fully reflected in Government purchases orin business fixed investment; some <strong>of</strong> it showed up as inventory investment.The impact <strong>of</strong> defense orders on inventories cannot be quantified precisely.But it can be estimated by two approaches: one uses data on progress paymentsmade by <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Defense, and <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r rests mainly on<strong>the</strong> statistics <strong>of</strong> defense-oriented industries. Both approaches suggest that,from <strong>the</strong> beginning <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> fourth quarter <strong>of</strong> 1965 through <strong>the</strong> third quarter<strong>of</strong> 1966, defense contractors and <strong>the</strong>ir suppliers added about $2 billion to<strong>the</strong>ir stocks as a result <strong>of</strong> defense orders.MONEY AND CREDITThe composition <strong>of</strong> output and <strong>the</strong> pace <strong>of</strong> advance last year were muchinfluenced by financial and credit developments. In 1966, monetary policymoved to <strong>the</strong> center <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> stage. Previously, it had played a significantrole in support <strong>of</strong> an active fiscal policy to stimulate economic expansion.52


PROMOTING EXPANSION, 1961 TO 1965From 1961 through 1965, Federal Reserve policy permitted a sufficientexpansion <strong>of</strong> credit to accommodate expanding demands for funds at onlymoderately rising interest rates. As in any period <strong>of</strong> economic advance,greatly increased credit was demanded by consumers to purchase homes anddurable goods, businesses to finance investment in plant and equipment andinventories, and State and local authorities to support <strong>the</strong>ir expenditures.In 1965, <strong>the</strong> net flow <strong>of</strong> new credit to <strong>the</strong>se groups was $66 billion—nearlydouble <strong>the</strong> amount in 1961 (Table 4).The pattern <strong>of</strong> credit flows had several outstanding characteristics. Thevolume <strong>of</strong> corporate security issues actually declined; with <strong>the</strong> very rapidgrowth <strong>of</strong> corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its, internal funds nearly kept pace with <strong>the</strong> expansion<strong>of</strong> business investment until mid-1965 (Chart 3). Also, <strong>the</strong>volume <strong>of</strong> security issues was held down by <strong>the</strong> ready availability <strong>of</strong> bankloans to business.The share <strong>of</strong> commercial banks in total lending rose by nearly one-thirdfrom 1961 to 1965, while <strong>the</strong> share <strong>of</strong> thrift institutions (savings and loanassociations and mutual savings banks) declined by nearly one-third. Followinga series <strong>of</strong> upward adjustments by regulatory authorities in <strong>the</strong> maximuminterest rates allowed on time and savings deposits, commercial bankscompeted aggressively for time deposits and acquired funds to meet growingdemands for loans. They developed and made effective use <strong>of</strong> some newfinancial instruments, especially <strong>the</strong> negotiable certificate <strong>of</strong> deposit (CD).Because <strong>the</strong>se certificates, unlike ordinary time deposits, can be readilysold, holders can earn interest on idle deposits without sacrificing liquidity.These innovations helped to hold down long-term interest rates in <strong>the</strong> face <strong>of</strong>TABLE 4.—Net funds raised by domestic nonfinancial sectors, 1961-66Type <strong>of</strong> credit1961[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]1962196319641965Total i1966FirsthalfSecondhalf*Private domestic nonfinancial sectorsConsumer creditBank loans 2State and local obligationsCorporate securitiesHome mortgages 8O<strong>the</strong>r*U.S. Government33.91.72.24.97.111.46.77.744.25.54.85.05.113.010.97.950.27.35.46.73.615.212.05.055.68.06.55.95.415.714.27.066.09.413.67.45.416.014.23.558.77.07.45.710.912.315.47.4Seasonally adjustedannualrates70.07.811.46.413.614.416.19.047.86.23.75.18.210.214.65.81 Preliminary estimates.2 Bank loans not elsewhere classified.3 Mortgages on 1- to 4-family homes.4 Acceptances, commercial and finance company paper, U.S. Government loans, and mortgages on multifamilydwellings and on farm and commercial land and buildings.Source: Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System.53


Chart 3BILLIONS OF DOLLARS80Investment and Gross Saving <strong>of</strong>Nonfinancial CorporationsSEASONALLY ADJUSTED ANNUAL RATES60~ ~ CROSS JAVWG2/ni i i 1 1 i i 1 1 i i 1 1 i i 1 1 i i 1 1 i i r1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966J/FIXED INVESTMENT PLUS CHANGE IN INVENTORIES.2/CORPORATE PROFITS AND INVENTORY VALUATION ADJUSTMENT, LESS PROFITS TAX ACCRUALS ANDDIVIDEND PAYMENTS, PLUS CAPITAL CONSUMPTION ALLOWANCES,SOURCE: BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM.growing credit demands, and supported continued expansion <strong>of</strong> economicactivity.SHIFT TO RESTRAINTConditions changed dramatically in <strong>the</strong> closing months <strong>of</strong> 1965. Therapid rise <strong>of</strong> business investment far exceeded <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> corporatecash flow. This widening gap, shown in Chart 3, was <strong>the</strong> major drivingforce behind <strong>the</strong> rising demand for credit that continued into <strong>the</strong> firsthalf <strong>of</strong> 1966. Given <strong>the</strong> intensity <strong>of</strong> this demand, monetary policy couldhave prevented an increase in interest rates and a tightening <strong>of</strong> credit availabilityonly by creating bank reserves at an extremely rapid rate. Such apolicy would have contributed to inflation by removing financial limitationson <strong>the</strong> surging demands for goods and services. Under <strong>the</strong> circumstances,it was desirable to curb <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> credit. The appropriate degree <strong>of</strong>restraint had to take into account <strong>the</strong> volume <strong>of</strong> pressure on financial54


markets and <strong>the</strong> magnitude <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> upward movement in interest rates thatcould be tolerated.In December 1965, <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve signaled <strong>the</strong> forthcoming tightening<strong>of</strong> monetary policy by increasing <strong>the</strong> discount rate from 4 percent to4J4 percent. At <strong>the</strong> same time, <strong>the</strong> maximum allowable interest rate ontime deposits <strong>of</strong> commercial banks was raised from 4^4 to 5}4 percent.During <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong> 1966, business demands for credit rose rapidly. Supplies<strong>of</strong> credit did not keep pace, as <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve held <strong>the</strong> expansionin bank reserves somewhat below that <strong>of</strong> 1965, when credit demands wererising less strongly.In order to maintain <strong>the</strong> good will <strong>of</strong> valued business customers, banksmade every effort to satisfy <strong>the</strong> mounting demands for business loans. Theyobtained additional loanable funds by increasing <strong>the</strong>ir borrowings from <strong>the</strong>Federal Reserve, reducing <strong>the</strong>ir investments in securities, bringing backfunds from <strong>the</strong>ir foreign branches, and attracting additional time depositsthrough higher interest rates. As a result, <strong>the</strong>y were able to expand businessloans at an annual rate <strong>of</strong> about 20 percent in <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong> 1966, even morerapidly than <strong>the</strong> 18 percent increase in 1965.Corporate demands for credit were so strong that even this extraordinaryincrease in bank lending provided less than half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> external fundsraised by corporations. To finance <strong>the</strong>ir investment expenditures, firms beganto issue large amounts <strong>of</strong> new securities. Sales <strong>of</strong> securities by <strong>the</strong>Government, particularly Government agencies, were also large duringthis period.The large volume <strong>of</strong> corporate and Government securities could be soldonly at much higher yields. After November 1965 interest rates on highgradesecurities increased sharply (Chart 4). As in <strong>the</strong> past, <strong>the</strong> rise inmarket yields, relative to <strong>the</strong> rates paid on deposits, permitted security issuesto absorb a larger proportion <strong>of</strong> total household lending (Chart 5). As ino<strong>the</strong>r periods <strong>of</strong> tight money and rising security yields, funds deposited infinancial institutions declined relative to funds provided directly to <strong>the</strong>security markets.COMPETITION AMONG FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONSCommercial banks competed strongly and ra<strong>the</strong>r successfully to hold<strong>the</strong>ir own as <strong>the</strong> total flow <strong>of</strong> funds into depository institutions declined.By raising yields on CD's, <strong>the</strong> banks attracted corporate time deposits inlarge volume. In addition, through <strong>the</strong> expanded use <strong>of</strong> savings certificatesand o<strong>the</strong>r types <strong>of</strong> nonnegotiable certificates <strong>of</strong> deposit, <strong>the</strong>y inducedan increasing flow <strong>of</strong> household time deposits.The impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> increased direct flow <strong>of</strong> savings to security marketsfell heavily on <strong>the</strong> thrift institutions. Thrift institutions continued to receive<strong>the</strong> deposits <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> steady savers who represent a major part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir clientele.55


Chart 4PERCENT8Selected Interest Rates- J^CONVENTIONAL MORTGAGESON HOMESV m —^ ^ ••••» •" «^ ^ mmm ^ «.* *PRIME BANKRATE\ CORPORATE Aao BONDS(New Issues)/ V3-MONTH TREASURY BILLS(New Issues)I lilt . I; 1 I , . 1 . • l u l l . 1 , ,1 • I I Ml, , I.H1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966Jl/NEW AND EXISTING HOMES THROUGH 1960 I, AND NEW HOMES ONLY THEREAFTER.NOTE.-DATA PLOTTED ARE QUARTERLY THROUGH 1963, MONTHLY THEREAFTER.SOURCES: FEDERAL HOUSING ADMINISTRATION, BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVESYSTEM, MOODY'S INVESTORS SERVICE, AND TREASURY DEPARTMENTIndeed, <strong>the</strong> gross inflow to savings and loan associations actually was largerin 1966 than in 1965. But, funds <strong>of</strong> interest-sensitive depositors (so-called"hot money") were withdrawn and invested in higher-yielding securities.These withdrawals dominated <strong>the</strong> net inflow. By mid-1966, <strong>the</strong> net inflowhad fallen to a rate less than one-fourth that <strong>of</strong> 1965.Unlike banks, thrift institutions were unable to prevent withdrawals effectivelyby raising interest rates paid on deposits. Because <strong>the</strong> portfolios <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong>se institutions were invested primarily in mortgages (assets with a fixedyield and a very slow turnover), <strong>the</strong>y had relatively little flexibility in adjusting<strong>the</strong> rates paid on ordinary deposits. Nor have thrift institutions madeeffective use <strong>of</strong> special savings certificates, which—like bank CD's—<strong>of</strong>fer


Chart 5PERCENTAGE POINTSInterest Rate Differentials and HouseholdSecurity PurchasesPERCENT2.00 | 11001.50EXCESS OF. CORPORATE Aaa RATE OVERTIME AND SAVINGS RATE-U(Left scale)751.0050.5025-50HOUSEHOLD INVESTMENT IN SECURITIES ASPERCENT OF TOTAL HOUSEHOLD GROSSFINANCIAL. INVESTMENT(Right scale)I I I I I I I I I I I I-251952 1954 1956 1958 1960 1962 1964 1966-^EXCESS OF CORPORATE Aaa BOND RATE (NEW ISSUES) OVER WEIGHTED AVERAGE OF INTERESTRATES PAID ON TIME AND SAVINGS DEPOSITS AND SHARE ACCOUNTS AT COMMERCIAL BANKSAND SAVINGS INSTITUTIONS.SOURCES: BOARD. OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM, FEDERAL DEPOSITINSURANCE CORPORATION, FEDERAL HOME LOAN BANK BOARD, AND COUNCIL OFECONOMIC ADVISERS.higher interest rates marginally without increasing <strong>the</strong> yield to all depositors.If <strong>the</strong>y had tried to remain competitive with banks by raising <strong>the</strong> rates paidon all deposits, <strong>the</strong>ir expenses would have risen much more rapidly than<strong>the</strong>ir income.With a greatly reduced inflow <strong>of</strong> funds, thrift institutions had to curtailmortgage lending sharply in 1966. Net acquisitions <strong>of</strong> residential mortgagesdecreased by 25 percent in <strong>the</strong> first two quarters <strong>of</strong> 1966. This reductionoccurred despite significant Government aid: <strong>the</strong> Federal National MortgageAssociation purchased nearly $4/ 2 billion <strong>of</strong> mortgages (annual rate) during<strong>the</strong> period, and <strong>the</strong> Home Loan Banks provided funds to <strong>of</strong>fset deposit losses<strong>of</strong> savings and loan associations. In <strong>the</strong> third quarter, only $9.4 billion (annualrate) went into residential mortgages—more than 40 percent below <strong>the</strong>amount provided a year earlier. The net flow into home mortgages fromsavings and loan associations was virtually zero. The result <strong>of</strong> all this was<strong>the</strong> marked decline in residential construction described earlier.57


In <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year, Federal Reserve policy restrained bank lendingonly moderately but placed o<strong>the</strong>r financial institutions under severe pressure.If monetary policy had been applied more restrictively to banks byproviding a smaller increase in reserves through open market operations,banks would have sold more securties and bid more aggressively for timedeposits. In that event, pressure on thrift institutions would have been evenmore extreme than it was in fact. In view <strong>of</strong> this, monetary policy wastempered by <strong>the</strong> intense competition among financial institutions.ACTIONS TO REDUCE FINANCIAL PRESSURESThe Federal Reserve acted after midyear to curb this intense competition.In July, interest rate ceilings were lowered on selected types <strong>of</strong> time deposits,and reserve requirements on time deposits were raised.Banks were also put under pressure during <strong>the</strong> summer as market interestrates rose fur<strong>the</strong>r and those on CD's moved up to <strong>the</strong> permissible 5^ percentceiling, curtailing <strong>the</strong> ability <strong>of</strong> banks to retain corporate time deposits.Meanwhile <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve tightened its open market operations, reducingnonborrowed reserves by $300 million between July and August. Interestrates rose sharply and, by late August, all sectors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> financial marketswere under severe pressure. Banks, faced with a declining reserve baseand unable to obtain corporate funds through CD's, were obliged to slowdown <strong>the</strong>ir lending. Thrift institutions, fearing a loss <strong>of</strong> funds, sharply curtailednew mortgage commitments.In September, <strong>the</strong> Administration, <strong>the</strong> Congress, and financial regulatoryagencies all took actions to improve <strong>the</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> demands for bothfunds and goods.The Federal Reserve, on September 1, asked member banks to cooperatein moderating <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> lending to business and spelled out its own currentpolicies regarding lending to member banks. Banks that cooperated in holdingdown business loan commitments and refrained from liquidating securitieswould be permitted to borrow funds from <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve forsomewhat longer periods than usual, while making necessary adjustments.The Federal Reserve fur<strong>the</strong>r increased <strong>the</strong> reserve requirement on timedeposits.The <strong>President</strong>'s proposal for temporary suspension <strong>of</strong> tax incentives toinvestment was designed to reduce corporate demands for long-term funds.The Administration also buoyed financial markets by indicating that Federalagencies would hold down stringently <strong>the</strong>ir issues <strong>of</strong> securities in <strong>the</strong>financial markets, even for purposes <strong>of</strong> refunding maturing issues.On September 21, <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> signed a bill allowing Federal regulatoryauthorities to impose new interest rate ceilings on time and savings accounts.In order to restrain excessive rate competition among different types <strong>of</strong>financial institutions, <strong>the</strong> agencies involved announced new interest rateregulations on <strong>the</strong> same day that <strong>the</strong> bill was signed.58


The interest rate that commercial banks were permitted to pay on deposits<strong>of</strong> less than $100,000 was reduced from 5 J4 percent to 5 percent. A 5 percentinterest rate ceiling was also imposed on <strong>the</strong> deposits <strong>of</strong> mutual savingsbanks. Because <strong>the</strong> rates paid by savings and loan associations varied widelyamong different parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> country, <strong>the</strong> regulations governing <strong>the</strong>se institutionswere considerably more complicated, but in general <strong>the</strong> ceilings wereset somewhat above <strong>the</strong> comparable ones for commercial banks.The flow <strong>of</strong> funds into mortgages was also supported by ano<strong>the</strong>r piece <strong>of</strong>legislation signed <strong>the</strong> same month, which increased <strong>the</strong> lending ability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Federal National Mortgage Association by a total <strong>of</strong> $4.8 billion.These various actions reflected widespread concern over <strong>the</strong> uneven impact<strong>of</strong> monetary policy actions and changing credit demands on differentsectors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> market.SIGNS OF RELAXATIONSince September, financial conditions have improved considerably. Themoderation in <strong>the</strong> pace <strong>of</strong> economic activity began to be reflected in lessintense demands for credit. As inflationary pressures abated, monetarypolicy responded promptly to <strong>the</strong> changing economic climate, and nonborrowedreserves resumed <strong>the</strong>ir growth in November and December.Moreover, <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve in late December rescinded <strong>the</strong> Septemberletter requesting banks to restrict business loans.After touching in late August and early September <strong>the</strong> highest levels inmore than 40 years, interest rates fell steadily. By <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year,most major interest rates on securities were appreciably below <strong>the</strong>ir earlierpeaks. The Treasury bill rate fell to about 4% percent, from more than5 J/2 percent in September. Rates on new issues <strong>of</strong> high grade corporate andmunicipal bonds declined by about one-half percentage point.The reduction in market interest rates and in <strong>the</strong> ceilings on rates <strong>of</strong>depository institutions has begun to restore balance among financial intermediaries.Mutual savings banks gained deposits at an annual rate <strong>of</strong>more than 6}4 percent in <strong>the</strong> latter part <strong>of</strong> 1966. Savings and loan associationstook longer to recover, but by December <strong>the</strong>re was definite improvement.In <strong>the</strong> first 11 months <strong>of</strong> 1966, <strong>the</strong> net inflow <strong>of</strong> funds was 72 percentbelow a year earlier. In December, however, a substantial net inflow <strong>of</strong>$1.7 billion exceeded that <strong>of</strong> December 1965.Commercial bank credit fell from August to October, bottomed out inNovember; in December it rebounded at an annual rate <strong>of</strong> 9 percent, returningto its August level. However, bank lending continued to be conservativeat year end, as many banks felt a need to rebuild <strong>the</strong>ir liquidityposition before expanding <strong>the</strong>ir loan commitments.As a result <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> moderation in economic activity and <strong>the</strong> flexible response<strong>of</strong> monetary policy, a welcome movement toward easier monetaryconditions began to emerge as 1966 closed.59


EVALUATION OF MONETARY RESTRAINTThe credit squeeze <strong>of</strong> 1966 had an impressive and beneficial restrainingeffect on over-all demand. Its side effects were equally impressive but farless beneficial.These side effects explain in part why relaxation <strong>of</strong> credit conditions isand has been an objective <strong>of</strong> policy. The cause <strong>of</strong> equity was not served by<strong>the</strong> arbitrary redistribution <strong>of</strong> income produced by very high interest rates orby <strong>the</strong> adversity experienced in <strong>the</strong> homebuilding industry. Moreover, <strong>the</strong>stability <strong>of</strong> financial markets was at times endangered. While <strong>the</strong> insurance<strong>of</strong> deposits and <strong>the</strong> powers <strong>of</strong> "lenders <strong>of</strong> last resort" gave full protectionagainst any recurrence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> financial panics experienced in previous generations,<strong>the</strong> liquidity <strong>of</strong> portfolios was impaired by rapidly rising interest rates.Last August, monetary policy was probably as tight as it could get withoutrisking financial disorder. Any fur<strong>the</strong>r increase in over-all demand couldnot have been effectively countered by general monetary policy. In sucha situation, <strong>the</strong> flexibility <strong>of</strong> over-all stabilization policy is impaired. It isdesirable for both fiscal and monetary policies to be operating from positionswhere <strong>the</strong>y can move freely ei<strong>the</strong>r way—toward stimulus or restraint in <strong>the</strong>event <strong>of</strong> unanticipated developments.The main effect <strong>of</strong> tight money on over-all activity worked primarilythrough <strong>the</strong> mortgage market, curtailing homebuilding and o<strong>the</strong>r mortgagefinancedconstruction. In December, expenditures for residential structureswere $7 billion (annual rate) below <strong>the</strong> first quarter level. Homebuildinghad been on a plateau during most <strong>of</strong> 1965 and was risingmoderately at <strong>the</strong> start <strong>of</strong> 1966. Demand conditions for housing lookedfairly encouraging as excess supplies <strong>of</strong> new housing (especially apartments)that had earlier appeared in certain areas were reduced moderately during1965. In <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> tight money, residential construction might haverisen slightly fur<strong>the</strong>r or retreated modestly during <strong>the</strong> course <strong>of</strong> 1966; <strong>the</strong>decline that actually occurred is a reasonable estimate <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>change in credit conditions. By similar reasoning, <strong>the</strong> performance <strong>of</strong> commercialand o<strong>the</strong>r mortgage-financed types <strong>of</strong> construction suggests an impact<strong>of</strong> perhaps $1 billion or more. Monetary restraint probably also had somemodest effect on expenditures for producers' durable equipment and consumerdurables, but <strong>the</strong> amount is not evident in aggregate data.All in all, it seems reasonable—perhaps even conservative—to estimatethat credit-financed expenditures may have been held down directly byas much as $8 billion at year-end as a result <strong>of</strong> tight money, compared withwhat would have happened had monetary policies continued supportive,as during 1964 and most <strong>of</strong> 1965. This direct impact <strong>of</strong> $8 billion onGNP is roughly as great as <strong>the</strong> estimated direct impact from a 10 percent surchargeon personal and corporate tax liabilities. (By restraining incomes,both tax increases and tight money have fur<strong>the</strong>r indirect "multiplier" effectson GNP.) Thus, when monetary restraint is taken into account, it becomes6o


clear that <strong>the</strong> combined impact <strong>of</strong> monetary and fiscal policy was markedlyrestrictive.PROSPECTS AND POLICIES FOR 1967As 1967 begins, over-all demand is reflecting <strong>the</strong> restraint <strong>of</strong> last year'smonetary and tax actions. Excessive demand is not now a serious threat.The economy's advance is being stimulated by a continuing rise in Federaldefense and State and local purchases. In <strong>the</strong> private sector, significantincreases should be registered in consumption. Modest advances are indicatedfor business fixed investment and for net exports, which reversed along decline in <strong>the</strong> fourth quarter <strong>of</strong> 1966.Data on housing starts and permits for <strong>the</strong> closing months <strong>of</strong> 1966 provideencouraging, although not conclusive, evidence that homebuilding activityhas touched bottom. But <strong>the</strong> recovery <strong>of</strong> homebuilding will take considerabletime, and <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> last year's monetary restraint will still befelt for many months. Interest rates on securities have declined; but revitalizedflows<strong>of</strong> funds into banks and thrift institutions have just begun. Financialinstitutions are relaxing <strong>the</strong>ir lending policies only gradually as <strong>the</strong>yrebuild liquidity. Interest rates on bank loans and mortgages have not yetreflected <strong>the</strong> easing in financial markets. Finally, construction expenditureswill take place only after contracts are placed and work is initiated.Inventory investment is bound to be considerably below <strong>the</strong> unusually highrate in <strong>the</strong> closing months <strong>of</strong> 1966. The rate <strong>of</strong> accumulation in <strong>the</strong> fourthquarter was about double that required to keep stocks advancing in pacewith <strong>the</strong> trend growth <strong>of</strong> sales. As in <strong>the</strong> earlier months <strong>of</strong> 1966, much <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> latest advance in inventories seems to have taken place in goods-inprocessheld by industries producing defense and business equipment; <strong>the</strong>buildup may continue but probably at a diminished rate.Thus, <strong>the</strong> economy faces a transition to a lower rate <strong>of</strong> investment ininventories. The strength elsewhere in <strong>the</strong> economy <strong>of</strong>fers important evidencethat <strong>the</strong> inventory adjustment need not cumulate into an excessiveslowdown <strong>of</strong> activity. The over-all assessment does suggest, however, thatprivate demand is not likely to be particularly buoyant in <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong>1967 and that a stimulative stabilization policy is appropriate to supportsteady expansion during this period.FISCAL PROGRAM FOR 1967The budget will be appropriately stimulative in <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong> 1967.The annual rate <strong>of</strong> deficit (national income accounts basis) is expected to bemore than $5 billion, compared with a $2/ 2 billion deficit rate in <strong>the</strong> secondhalf <strong>of</strong> 1966. Although nondefense spending has been held down, both <strong>the</strong>special costs <strong>of</strong> Vietnam and fur<strong>the</strong>r increases in transfer payments forMedicare will add substantially to Federal outlays. Revenues will continue240-782 O—67^—56i


<strong>the</strong>ir normal growth in <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong> 1967; but, unlike 1966, no significantnet changes in tax payments will result from recent legislation. An increasein payroll taxes <strong>of</strong> $l*/2 billion (annual rate), which went into effect at <strong>the</strong>beginning <strong>of</strong> 1967, will be nearly <strong>of</strong>fset by <strong>the</strong> effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> system <strong>of</strong>graduated withholding on income tax collections. As a result <strong>of</strong> thissystem, which was instituted last May, an additional $1 billion in personaltaxes was collected during 1966. Reflecting this, net final paymentsthis spring on personal tax liabilities for 1966 are expected to be correspondinglysmaller.By midyear, construction should be recovering with <strong>the</strong> stimulus <strong>of</strong> monetaryease; and inventory investment should be leveling <strong>of</strong>f at a moderaterate. In combination, <strong>the</strong>se two sectors should significantly streng<strong>the</strong>nover-all private demand. A shift toward restraint in fiscal policy is appropriateat that time to assure that demand does not outrun capacity, thatmovement toward restoration <strong>of</strong> price stability is maintained, and thatmonetary policy does not have to be tightened again.In line with this set <strong>of</strong> aims, <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> is asking <strong>the</strong> Congress to enact,as <strong>of</strong> midyear, a 6 percent surcharge on personal and corporate income taxliabilities with an exemption for low-income families. The tax will remainin effect for 2 years or as long as <strong>the</strong> unusual special Vietnam costs continue.The form <strong>of</strong> this proposed temporary tax increase parallels <strong>the</strong> conclusion<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Subcommittee on Fiscal Policy <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Joint <strong>Economic</strong> Committeethat "... a uniform percentage addition to ... corporate and personalincome tax liabilities . . ., to be effective for a stated period, best satisfiescriteria for shortrun stabilizing revenue changes." Once fully in effect, <strong>the</strong>surcharge will drain <strong>of</strong>f an estimated $5.8 billion (annual rate) <strong>of</strong> privateincomes—$3.9 billion from individuals and $1.9 billion from corporations.On <strong>the</strong> expenditure side, defense purchases will continue to rise butat a diminishing rate during <strong>the</strong> course <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year. Transfer paymentsin <strong>the</strong> second half <strong>of</strong> 1967 will exceed <strong>the</strong> rate in <strong>the</strong> first half by $4j/ibillion, reflecting primarily <strong>the</strong> proposed increase in Social Security benefits.The <strong>President</strong> is requesting benefit liberalization amounting to $4 billion(annual rate) to begin by midyear, to support <strong>the</strong> needs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> elderly.The liberalization will be followed by an increase in <strong>the</strong> payroll tax base at<strong>the</strong> beginning <strong>of</strong> 1968. Reflecting <strong>the</strong> income tax surcharge, normal revenuegrowth, and increased expenditures, <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> budget deficit will bereduced to about $3 billion in <strong>the</strong> second half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year, and <strong>the</strong> budgetis expected to be approximately in balance in <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong> 1968.ECONOMIC OUTLOOKWith Congressional enactment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong>'s key fiscal proposals,GNP for 1967 is expected to reach $787 billion, given <strong>the</strong> $740 billionnow estimated for 1966. In <strong>the</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> economic forecasting, <strong>the</strong> projectedadvance <strong>of</strong> $47 billion must be viewed as <strong>the</strong> midpoint <strong>of</strong> a range<strong>of</strong> possible outcomes, ra<strong>the</strong>r than a precise estimate.62


Like any quantitative forecast, <strong>the</strong> estimated rise <strong>of</strong> $47 billion is meantto convey important qualitative judgments. The advance will be considerablyless rapid than <strong>the</strong> record increase <strong>of</strong> $58 billion in GNP in 1966.Healthy forward motion will never<strong>the</strong>less be maintained. Real outputshould expand nearly in line with <strong>the</strong> 4 percent growth <strong>of</strong> potential. As explainedin Chapter 2, <strong>the</strong> price record should improve; over-all prices mayincrease slightly more than 2 l /% percent. Finally and most important, <strong>the</strong>Nation should continue to experience substantially full employment in 1967.The unemployment rate should be essentially <strong>the</strong> same as in 1966, when itaveraged 3.9 percent. After allowance for an increase <strong>of</strong> more than 300,000in <strong>the</strong> Armed Forces, <strong>the</strong> civilian labor force should expand by about 1J4million, and civilian employment should approximately keep pace.Outlook by SectorsA more balanced composition <strong>of</strong> output is expected in 1967, reflecting<strong>the</strong> aims and effects <strong>of</strong> policy. Nei<strong>the</strong>r business fixed investment nor inventoryinvestment will, or should, be strong stimulating forces. On <strong>the</strong>o<strong>the</strong>r hand, housing should gain as <strong>the</strong> year develops, and defense outlayswill continue to provide economic stimulus.Business Fixed Investment. After increasing by an average <strong>of</strong> 13^2percent annually over <strong>the</strong> past 3 years, business fixed investment shouldexpand much more slowly in 1967. Evidence <strong>of</strong> this is already providedin <strong>the</strong> November survey <strong>of</strong> intentions for plant and equipment spending.Investment should increase only slightly from its level in <strong>the</strong> fourth quarter<strong>of</strong> 1966, and should show a rise <strong>of</strong> about $3 billion from 1966 to 1967. Thispace would be a welcome respite, permitting pressures on capital goods industriesto abate. The ratio <strong>of</strong> business investment to GNP should declineslowly to a more sustainable level near 10*4 percent by year end.Business Inventories. Inventory investment was at a record high lastyear, partly because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rise in goods-in-process stocks <strong>of</strong> industriesproducing business and defense equipment. Any fur<strong>the</strong>r buildup <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>sestocks will be small. Stocks in most areas are expected to rise in line withsteady and moderate advances in sales. Inventory investment for 1967 maybe about half <strong>the</strong> $11 J/a billion rate experienced in 1966. Most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> declineto a sustainable rate should occur in <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year, with a leveling<strong>of</strong>f <strong>the</strong>reafter.Homebuilding. As monetary policy continues to ease, housing startsshould begin to rise above <strong>the</strong>ir current depressed level. Additional helpshould come from actions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Home Loan Bank Board(FHLBB) and <strong>the</strong> Federal National Mortgage Association (FNMA).Because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> lag between mortgage commitments and construction expenditures,activity should begin to increase very gradually in <strong>the</strong> first half<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year and gain considerable momentum in <strong>the</strong> latter part. Demo-


graphic factors and low vacancy rates point to latent strength in homebuilding,which should become evident during <strong>the</strong> course <strong>of</strong> 1967.Residential construction expenditures are expected to increase by about$5 billion to $6 billion from <strong>the</strong> fourth quarter <strong>of</strong> 1966 to <strong>the</strong> fourth quarter<strong>of</strong> 1967. Even so, for <strong>the</strong> year as a whole, <strong>the</strong>y would still be about $1billion below <strong>the</strong> 1966 average.Government. State and local government purchases, which grew by 10percent, or $7 billion in 1966, should expand in 1967 by about $8 billion inresponse to growing needs and strongly increasing revenues. The increasein Federal purchases from 1966 to 1967 is expected to be $12 billion, mostlyfor defense. But <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> advance will taper <strong>of</strong>f during <strong>the</strong> course <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> year.Net Exports. As <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> imports moderates and exports showstrength, net exports should expand throughout <strong>the</strong> year, rising about $1billion from 1966 to 1967.Consumption. The fiscal program for 1967 will have a direct impact onafter-tax incomes <strong>of</strong> households and thus on <strong>the</strong>ir consumption outlays. Thegrowth in transfer payments will increase disposable income, while <strong>the</strong> proposedsurtax on individual incomes and <strong>the</strong> payroll tax that just took effectwill restrain it. The more moderate growth expected in employment and<strong>the</strong> net effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se policy measures will hold <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> disposablepersonal income in 1967 somewhat below <strong>the</strong> gain in 1966.This advance in disposable income should make possible a gain in consumption<strong>of</strong> more than $30 billion in 1967, compared with a rise <strong>of</strong> $33^4billion in 1966. In real terms, <strong>the</strong> expected gains in consumption anddisposable income in 1967 are expected approximately to match those <strong>of</strong>1966. The saving rate in 1967 should remain close to <strong>the</strong> 1966 level <strong>of</strong> 5}4percent, a little below <strong>the</strong> average <strong>of</strong> recent years.FlexibilityThe program and <strong>the</strong> outlook for 1967 provide good prospects for agrowth <strong>of</strong> demand that keeps pace with capacity. But <strong>the</strong> experience <strong>of</strong> 1966is a clear reminder that surprises can develop and that policy must be alertto <strong>the</strong>m. This year, <strong>the</strong> risks are on both sides: demand could grow toosluggishly or too strongly. A balance <strong>of</strong> risks is a necessary feature <strong>of</strong> afull employment economy moving ahead essentially in line with potential.In <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong> 1967, <strong>the</strong>re are forces which could make for sluggishprivate demand, but a sizable stimulus from fiscal policy will help to clear<strong>the</strong> hurdles. Then, in <strong>the</strong> second half, housing should move up strongly,<strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> inventory investment should stop declining, and transfer paymentswill rise. Indeed, with <strong>the</strong>se developments, private demand couldonce again move ahead rapidly, perhaps even too rapidly. But, by that time,<strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong>'s tax program will be moderating <strong>the</strong> advance.At any time in <strong>the</strong> year, <strong>the</strong> outlook for plant and equipment demandcould be upset if <strong>the</strong> recent signs <strong>of</strong> moderation should prove illusory or


if a sharp and pronounced decline should occur. Ei<strong>the</strong>r development couldcall for a response by stabilization policies.Cessation <strong>of</strong> hostilities in Vietnam would be <strong>the</strong> most welcome surprisethat could develop in 1967. It would challenge economic policy to smooth<strong>the</strong> transition—and policy will be ready to meet <strong>the</strong> challenge. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rhand, an unexpected increase in outlays required for defense would haveimportant consequences, pointing toward fur<strong>the</strong>r measures <strong>of</strong> restraint, particularlyfrom fiscal policy.A firm set <strong>of</strong> attainable objectives, a program that fits <strong>the</strong> present outlook,alertness to changing circumstances, and flexible and well-coordinated use<strong>of</strong> policy instruments are <strong>the</strong> necessary means for maintaining full employmentand achieving a sustainable advance in 1967.IMPROVING STABILIZATION TOOLS OVER THE LONGER RUNThe tools <strong>of</strong> economic stabilization now at our disposal can cope quiteeffectively with <strong>the</strong> problems that lie immediately ahead. Over <strong>the</strong> comingyears, however, <strong>the</strong>re is a continuing need to sharpen and improve <strong>the</strong>sepolicy tools—as well as <strong>the</strong> institutional framework within which <strong>the</strong>yoperate—so that short-term policy can respond efficiently and flexibly toeconomic fluctuations and simultaneously promote progress along a path <strong>of</strong>sustainable long-term growth.USES OF MONETARY POLICYAs a stabilization tool, monetary policy has some distinct advantages.Policy changes can be made quickly in response to changing signals. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore,as was evident in 1966, a restrictive monetary policy can reduceaggregate demand fairly promptly and very sharply.But <strong>the</strong>re are also distinct limitations on <strong>the</strong> uses <strong>of</strong> monetary policy.As demonstrated in 1966 its impact on different sectors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy canbe highly uneven, both in magnitude and in timing. Moreover, if monetarypolicy is used repeatedly and in large doses to restrain inflation, it maybe difficult to avoid a long-term upward trend in interest rates. And <strong>the</strong>scope for monetary policy may at times also be limited by balance <strong>of</strong> paymentsconsiderations.The uneven impact <strong>of</strong> changes in credit conditions is unavoidable to acertain extent. Monetary policy inevitably has its principal effect on thosesectors that are particularly dependent on credit. But <strong>the</strong> special vulnerability<strong>of</strong> some sectors to tightening is also importantly related to certainstructural characteristics <strong>of</strong> our financial institutions. Over time, <strong>the</strong>reshould be scope for reducing <strong>the</strong> uneven impact <strong>of</strong> monetary policy throughvarious modifications in <strong>the</strong>se institutional arrangements. This is particularlytrue with respect to homebuilding.In <strong>the</strong> postwar period, changing monetary conditions have contributed toseveral major swings in residential construction. This particularly sensi-65


tive reaction to monetary conditions reflects <strong>the</strong> reliance <strong>of</strong> mortgage financingon institutional ra<strong>the</strong>r than open market sources <strong>of</strong> credit and its specialreliance on one particular type <strong>of</strong> institution, namely savings and loan associations.The most recent example <strong>of</strong> this sensitivity, reviewed earlier, was in1966, when <strong>the</strong> associations suffered major withdrawals <strong>of</strong> funds.Until 1957, savings and loan associations were largely sheltered fromcompetition with commercial banks. Bank interest rates for time depositswere fixed at a low level, and most banks were not interested in competingfor savings funds. At that time, however, a series <strong>of</strong> increases was initiatedin <strong>the</strong> administrative ceilings on <strong>the</strong> interest rates that banks could pay ontime deposits. This led to a gradual narrowing in <strong>the</strong> differential betweenrates paid by <strong>the</strong> associations and by <strong>the</strong> banks; and <strong>the</strong> share <strong>of</strong> depositsgoing into savings and loan associations declined, even though <strong>the</strong> totalamount advanced rapidly, at least until 1966. Given <strong>the</strong> respective legallimitations on <strong>the</strong> portfolios <strong>of</strong> banks and <strong>of</strong> thrift institutions, such a shiftgradually tended to curtail <strong>the</strong> flow <strong>of</strong> funds to <strong>the</strong> mortgage market.There is every reason to believe that thrift institutions will continue to facestrong competition from banks, and must hereafter operate in a verydifferent environment from that prior to 1957.The supply <strong>of</strong> mortgage funds might be better protected in future periods<strong>of</strong> tight credit conditions if techniques could be devised to give <strong>the</strong> mortgagemarkets new and better forms <strong>of</strong> access to <strong>the</strong> open capital markets,ei<strong>the</strong>r directly or through <strong>the</strong> thrift institutions. A number <strong>of</strong> possible arrangementsare now under discussion in <strong>the</strong> industry. With such arrangements,funds would be available only at competitive rates; but <strong>the</strong>y would beavailable. At present, some access is obtained indirectly, when banks, insurancecompanies, and savings banks sell bonds in periods <strong>of</strong> tight moneyin order to buy mortgages. FNMA secondary market operations andFHLBB advances to savings and loan associations also provide an indirectlink between mortgage financing and <strong>the</strong> national capital market.Some additional stability in <strong>the</strong> flow <strong>of</strong> funds to <strong>the</strong> mortgage marketcould also be achieved through changes in <strong>the</strong> practices <strong>of</strong> savings and loanassociations. They could partially stabilize <strong>the</strong>ir mortgage lending activityin <strong>the</strong> face <strong>of</strong> fluctuations in deposit flows if <strong>the</strong>y held secondary reservesas commercial banks normally do. They can also place <strong>the</strong>mselves in abetter position to hold on to interest-sensitive deposits in a period <strong>of</strong> tightcredit by issuing special instruments, like CD's, returning a higher yield toinvestors. Comprehensive authority to issue such instruments has beengranted only recently and should be <strong>of</strong> additional help in <strong>the</strong> future. Inparticular, <strong>the</strong> associations reduce <strong>the</strong>ir exposure to abrupt changes in depositflows by issuing such instruments for longer maturities.It would also be desirable to streng<strong>the</strong>n thrift institutions by legislationpermitting <strong>the</strong> Federal chartering <strong>of</strong> mutual savings banks. Such institutionswould have powers to invest in corporate securities and con-66


sumer loans as well as mortgages. While broadened investment privileges <strong>of</strong>federally chartered mutual savings banks might initially divert some fundsfrom <strong>the</strong> mortgage market, such chartered banks would improve <strong>the</strong> efficiency<strong>of</strong> thrift institutions, streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>m in competition with banks, and<strong>the</strong>reby ultimately benefit <strong>the</strong> mortgage market.If <strong>the</strong> ability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> thrift institutions to compete with commercial bankscan be streng<strong>the</strong>ned, continuous reliance on interest rate ceilings onsavings accounts may no longer be desirable. But <strong>the</strong>re could still be occasionswhen rate ceilings would serve a genuine need. This contingencycould be provided for in ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>of</strong> two ways: (1) through standby authorityto impose rate ceilings under particular circumstances; or (2) throughpermanent ceilings set sufficiently high that <strong>the</strong>y would become effectiveonly in unusual instances. Pending agreement on <strong>the</strong> most suitable form<strong>of</strong> permanent legislation for regulating rates, <strong>the</strong> present legislation (whichexpires in September) should be continued for a limited period.The kinds <strong>of</strong> financial innovations sketched above could increase <strong>the</strong>scope for <strong>the</strong> active use <strong>of</strong> monetary policy as a tool <strong>of</strong> stabilization. Withsuch changes, a restrictive monetary policy might have a broader and lessuneven impact.There are, however, o<strong>the</strong>r possible limitations on <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> monetarypolicy. There is <strong>the</strong> danger that under some circumstances, employment <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> monetary instrument for short-run stabilization purposes can producean upward ratcheting <strong>of</strong> interest rates which could interfere with long-termeconomic growth.Indeed, in <strong>the</strong> postwar period, cyclical movements in rates have beensuperimposed on a distinct upward rate trend. Every period <strong>of</strong> businessexpansion has brought new postwar peaks in interest rates. Of course,rates were abnormally low at <strong>the</strong> start <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> postwar era, reflecting <strong>the</strong>unusually large liquid balances <strong>of</strong> businesses and households. But thisinitial situation cannot explain <strong>the</strong> continuing upward trend in ratessince <strong>the</strong> mid-1950's. During each period <strong>of</strong> economic expansion in <strong>the</strong>1950's, credit was tightened sharply to restrain demand. The resulting increasesin interest rates were not fully <strong>of</strong>fset during <strong>the</strong> subsequent mildrecessions. With each advance, expectations became adjusted to <strong>the</strong>new level. Rigidities retarded declines, once higher rates were built into <strong>the</strong>deposit and loan practices <strong>of</strong> financial institutions.But an upward ratchet <strong>of</strong> interest rates is not an inherent or necessaryresult <strong>of</strong> a flexible monetary policy. There is now a welcome opportunityfor monetary policy to demonstrate its reversibility in a period <strong>of</strong> prosperity;indeed, that opportunity has already begun to be converted into reality.A variety <strong>of</strong> approaches can also be used to reduce some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> obstacles toa flexible use <strong>of</strong> monetary policy which may be imposed by balance <strong>of</strong> paymentsconsiderations, as discussed more fully in Chapter 5.Monetary policy is an indispensable tool; and <strong>the</strong>re is important scope formaking it more useful. But <strong>the</strong> measures that can be taken to this end can-


not fully overcome its inherent limitations. It needs, and has, a powerfulally in fiscal policy.NEED FOR FISCAL FLEXIBILITYIn any over-all stabilization program, fiscal policy must play a majorrole. Fiscal policy is generally more even in its impact than monetary policy.Its effects tend to be more readily predictable and less subject to time lags.Fiscal policy, too, can be used with a great deal <strong>of</strong> flexibility.In principle, a fiscal program for short-term stabilization can involveadjustment <strong>of</strong> budget expenditures, <strong>of</strong> tax rates, or <strong>of</strong> both. A limitedamount <strong>of</strong> discretionary expenditure variation within a given year canbe very useful to deal with unanticipated economic developments. Butmost economists now agree that <strong>the</strong> selection <strong>of</strong> appropriate expenditurelevels for various public programs in <strong>the</strong> budget should be made in light <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> relative merits <strong>of</strong> alternative programs, and <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> benefits <strong>of</strong> addedpublic expenditures, compared with private ones, at <strong>the</strong> margin. Although<strong>the</strong> timing <strong>of</strong> some Federal expenditures can be flexibly adjusted, only gradualchanges can be made in o<strong>the</strong>r programs without compromising <strong>the</strong>irefficiency, at least to a degree. For such reasons, it is preferable to emphasizechanges in tax rates (suitably coordinated with changes in monetarypolicy) for stabilization purposes, and to take full account <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> possibilities<strong>of</strong> tax and monetary adjustments in determining patterns and levels <strong>of</strong>public expenditures.A change in tax rates can have a powerful impact; but it usually neednot be applied in heavy doses. A large downward adjustment in tax rateswas needed in 1964, because fiscal policy had been permitted to tighten undulyover a period <strong>of</strong> many years. But if active fiscal policy is pursued continuously,only small adjustments in tax rates at any given time should beneeded in most peacetime situations. Willingness to consider making suchsmall adjustments frequently would contribute substantially to <strong>the</strong> effectiveness<strong>of</strong> stabilization policy and to efficient planning <strong>of</strong> Government programs.Indeed, this willingness seems already established: in each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>past 6 years, <strong>President</strong>s Kennedy and Johnson have called for significantchanges in tax laws. Annual tax changes have, in fact, become <strong>the</strong> rulera<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> exception.The very fact that tax rates are less stable than in <strong>the</strong> past helps to makefor a more stable economy. Far from being a source <strong>of</strong> increased uncertainty—asis sometimes alleged—<strong>the</strong> flexible and coordinated use <strong>of</strong> stabilizationpolicies should enable both business firms and individuals to make <strong>the</strong>ireconomic decisions in a climate <strong>of</strong> greater confidence. A knowledge thatpolicies are alert to changing developments should help to reduce <strong>the</strong> importantuncertainties about possible fluctuations in sales, pr<strong>of</strong>its, and employmentopportunities.68


AppendixTHE FEDERAL BUDGET, NATIONAL INCOME ACCOUNTS BASISThroughout this Annual <strong>Report</strong>, Federal receipts and expenditures andbudget surpluses or deficits are referred to in terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> national incomeaccounts (NIA) budget. This is a set <strong>of</strong> accounts devised by <strong>the</strong> Department<strong>of</strong> Commerce, as part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> national income statistics, to register <strong>the</strong>way that Federal fiscal transactions affect <strong>the</strong> income stream.The principles followed in <strong>the</strong> NIA budget are relatively simple. In <strong>the</strong>first place, this budget is comprehensive and records all Federal transactionsthat directly alter private spendable income including that <strong>of</strong> State and localgovernments. It incorporates <strong>the</strong> fiscal transactions <strong>of</strong> all Federal agencies,regardless <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> legal arrangements applying to <strong>the</strong>se agencies. Thus, <strong>the</strong>accounts include operations <strong>of</strong> trust funds and o<strong>the</strong>r Government-ownedagencies as well as regular Government departments.Second, Federal transactions are counted at <strong>the</strong> time that <strong>the</strong>y add to orsubtract from private spendable income, which <strong>of</strong>ten is different from <strong>the</strong>time when funds are actually withdrawn from or deposited into Treasuryaccounts.Third, all transactions involving loans or exchanges in assets are excluded.The Government engages in numerous lending and swapping transactionsinvolving billions <strong>of</strong> dollars a year. These are extremely important to<strong>the</strong> operation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy, but <strong>the</strong>y are not to be regarded as fiscaltransactions because <strong>the</strong>y do not affect disposable incomes directly.In following <strong>the</strong>se principles, <strong>the</strong> NIA budget differs in several importantrespects from <strong>the</strong> more familiar administrative budget. The administrativebudget is <strong>the</strong> traditional vehicle for <strong>the</strong> management and control <strong>of</strong> most<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal programs which operate through regular Congressional appropriations.But it does not, and was not designed to, reflect even approximately<strong>the</strong> economic impact <strong>of</strong> fiscal policy.For <strong>the</strong> calendar year 1966, <strong>the</strong> NIA budget was essentially balanced witha tiny surplus <strong>of</strong> $0.2 billion. But, in <strong>the</strong> administrative budget, expendituresoutran receipts by $7.3 billion. The main elements accounting for this verylarge difference are shown in Table 5. Particularly important were Federalnet loans and <strong>the</strong> net surplus <strong>of</strong> trust funds.Trust funds. The administrative budget generally excludes both <strong>the</strong> revenuesand expenditures <strong>of</strong> Federal trust funds. These funds include <strong>the</strong>


TABLE 5.—Relation <strong>of</strong> two measures <strong>of</strong> Federal budget surplus or deficit,calendar year 1966DescriptionSurplus or deficit (—), national income accounts budget.Plus: SeigniorageExcess <strong>of</strong> taxes received over taxes accruedMiscellaneous adjustments (net)Less: Excess <strong>of</strong> cash payments over goods received...Net loans and financial transactionsSurplus, Federal trust fundsEquals: Surplus or deficit (-), administrative budget....Billions <strong>of</strong>dollars0.2.91.41.01.06.63.2-7.3Sources: Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Budget and Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce.various Social Security, hospital insurance, and Medicare funds, unemploymentinsurance, railroad and civil service retirement funds, <strong>the</strong> highwaytrust fund, veterans life insurance, and many o<strong>the</strong>rs. Most transactions <strong>of</strong>trust funds directly affect <strong>the</strong> private income stream. Both expenditures andreceipts are very large, approximately $40 billion. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> funds canbe in substantial surplus or deficit in any year. In calendar 1966, <strong>the</strong>yshowed a net surplus <strong>of</strong> $3.2 billion. That surplus is properly reflected in <strong>the</strong>NIA budget, although ignored in <strong>the</strong> administrative budget. A third measure<strong>of</strong> Government financial transactions—<strong>the</strong> consolidated cash budget—corresponds in this respect with <strong>the</strong> NIA budget.Timing. In business accounting, which provides <strong>the</strong> framework fordecision-making by firms, purchases and sales <strong>of</strong> goods and services aretypically recorded when liabilities are incurred ra<strong>the</strong>r than when cashchanges hands. The NIA budget generally follows <strong>the</strong> same procedure.On <strong>the</strong> revenue side, withholding <strong>of</strong> personal income taxes is counted as acollection when <strong>the</strong> taxes are actually taken from <strong>the</strong> paychecks <strong>of</strong> employeesra<strong>the</strong>r than when employers pay <strong>the</strong> Government; excise and sales taxesare counted when <strong>the</strong> sales <strong>of</strong> taxable goods are actually made; and corporateincome taxes are counted when <strong>the</strong>y accrue. Similarly, on <strong>the</strong> expenditureside, Government purchases <strong>of</strong> goods from businesses are recorded at <strong>the</strong> time<strong>of</strong> delivery ra<strong>the</strong>r than at time <strong>of</strong> payment. In this respect, both <strong>the</strong> administrativebudget and <strong>the</strong> consolidated cash budget differ from standard businessaccounting treatment by adopting a cash basis for <strong>the</strong> timing <strong>of</strong>transactions.In 1966, cash collections <strong>of</strong> taxes exceeded accruals by about $1.4 billion,while cash disbursements for goods and services exceeded deliveries by$1.0 billion.Seigniorage. The NIA budget and <strong>the</strong> administrative budget also differin <strong>the</strong>ir treatment <strong>of</strong> Treasury pr<strong>of</strong>its on coinage operations (seigniorage),which amounted to $0.9 billion last year. When <strong>the</strong> face value <strong>of</strong> newcoins minted exceeds <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> metal used to produce <strong>the</strong>m, <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it iscounted as a receipt in <strong>the</strong> administrative budget. But it is not a Governmentreceipt in <strong>the</strong> NIA budget, because <strong>the</strong> increase in Treasury cash bal-70


ances which results is a purely internal Government bookkeeping entry whichdoes not reduce or drain <strong>of</strong>f private purchasing power.Lending. A fur<strong>the</strong>r and vital difference between <strong>the</strong> NIA budget, on <strong>the</strong>one hand, and <strong>the</strong> consolidated cash and administrative budgets, on <strong>the</strong>o<strong>the</strong>r, involves <strong>the</strong> treatment <strong>of</strong> lending, loan repayment, and sales <strong>of</strong> financialassets. Such financial transactions are excluded from <strong>the</strong> NIA budgetbecause <strong>the</strong>y do not change <strong>the</strong> net worth or incomes <strong>of</strong> private parties, butonly <strong>the</strong>ir liquidity. The reasoning follows <strong>the</strong> same line applied above totax accruals and pr<strong>of</strong>its on coinage. Just as businesses do not regard <strong>the</strong>mselvesas becoming poorer at <strong>the</strong> time <strong>the</strong>y actually pay taxes <strong>the</strong>y alreadyowe, nei<strong>the</strong>r do <strong>the</strong>y consider repaying a Government loan as a currentexpense. Nor conversely, do <strong>the</strong>ir incomes rise when <strong>the</strong>y obtain loans from<strong>the</strong> Federal Government. Yet, in <strong>the</strong> administrative budget a new Federalloan increases <strong>the</strong> deficit as much as an outlay that directly raises privateincome, and sale or repayment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> loan diminishes it just as much as atax payment.To be sure, many Federal loan transactions have important effects onprivate spending. But <strong>the</strong>y work in a less direct way than <strong>the</strong> incomegeneratingtransactions. They channel funds at low costs to various activitiesdeemed to be <strong>of</strong> particular social or economic importance, such asexports, college, housing, and farm production. Given <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> taxrevenues, when <strong>the</strong> Government lends more, it must also borrow more. Thenet impact <strong>of</strong> a Federal loan financed by Government borrowing is thatGovernment liabilities—Treasury and agency issues—are substituted forprivate debts.Such substitution is likely to improve <strong>the</strong> terms and • lower <strong>the</strong> interestrates available to some borrowers. But o<strong>the</strong>r borrowers may be displaced,depending on credit conditions and monetary policy. Federal lending isbest regarded as an aspect <strong>of</strong> monetary, credit, and debt managementpolicy—not <strong>of</strong> fiscal policy. When it lends borrowed funds, <strong>the</strong> Governmentis acting as a financial institution, much like private financial institutions.Borrowers from private financial institutions also increase <strong>the</strong>ir liquidity.They acquire cash by incurring debts. They are, indeed, better <strong>of</strong>f for <strong>the</strong>opportunities to borrow, and <strong>the</strong>y may spend more as a result; but <strong>the</strong>y donot regard <strong>the</strong> borrowing as an addition to <strong>the</strong>ir incomes.In <strong>the</strong> past year, <strong>the</strong> Federal Government was a net lender, partly because<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> scarcity <strong>of</strong> funds in private financial markets. The difference between<strong>the</strong> two budgets on this account amounted to $6.6 billion.


Chapter 2Prices and Wages in 1966Expanding production and fuller employment brought gratifying advancesin <strong>the</strong> incomes <strong>of</strong> most Americans in 1966. But satisfactionwith higher incomes was marred by concern over <strong>the</strong> first significant rise inprices in 7 years.The shift away from price stability actually began early in 1965, whensagging farm prices suddenly reversed direction, followed shortly by a climbin food prices, first at wholesale and <strong>the</strong>n at retail. During <strong>the</strong> course <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> year, prices <strong>of</strong> many o<strong>the</strong>r items turned upward. But it was only in 1966that price movements were sufficiently disturbing to arouse public concern.The public sensed what every economist knows—that a reasonably stableprice level is essential if balanced prosperity and full employment are to becontinued at home and if <strong>the</strong> strength <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> dollar is to be maintainedabroad. Experience proves that rising prices can generate distortions thatcan eventually topple an economy from boom to recession. Experiencealso shows that rapidly rising prices can quickly erode a country's competitiveposition in international markets. The critical economic problem to besolved in <strong>the</strong> year ahead is that <strong>of</strong> maintaining income growth and fullutilization <strong>of</strong> resources without becoming trapped in an inflationary pricewagespiral.The recent advance in prices was due in large measure to <strong>the</strong> accelerationin <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> demand which began in mid-1965 and to <strong>the</strong> particularlyrapid increase in output <strong>of</strong> capital goods and defense products. The step-upin <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> price increase cannot be explained by any simple formula.It was a by-product <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> complex process by which additional resourcesare drawn into production and adapted to <strong>the</strong> changing composition <strong>of</strong>demand. That process is now largely completed, leaving <strong>the</strong> economy witha much higher rate <strong>of</strong> utilization <strong>of</strong> resources. But in <strong>the</strong> process <strong>of</strong> adjustment,forces were set in motion which will continue to push up prices for atime even though <strong>the</strong> pressure on resources has now relaxed.Demand had, <strong>of</strong> course, been rising steadily since 1961. But that risebegan when <strong>the</strong>re were abundant supplies <strong>of</strong> idle labor and unused equipment.In addition, productive capacity was being steadily increased through<strong>the</strong> installation <strong>of</strong> new plant and equipment; accretions to <strong>the</strong> labor force;72


and <strong>the</strong> steady rise <strong>of</strong> productivity as a result <strong>of</strong> better management, anincreasingly educated and skilled work force, new industrial processes, andincreased capital per worker. Thus, throughout <strong>the</strong> early 1960's productioncould expand freely to match growing demand. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> pattern<strong>of</strong> expansion <strong>of</strong> industrial capacity was well balanced with <strong>the</strong> pattern <strong>of</strong>rising demand, so that few specific points <strong>of</strong> pressure on <strong>the</strong> price structuredeveloped.By mid-1965, prices <strong>of</strong> farm products and <strong>of</strong> some industrial raw materialswere already rising, partly because <strong>of</strong> growing demand, but als<strong>of</strong>or such unrelated reasons on <strong>the</strong> supply side as <strong>the</strong> stage <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> hog productioncycle or impediments to minerals production abroad. Moreover, bythat time, margins <strong>of</strong> idle labor and underutilized plant and equipmentwere shrinking. Under <strong>the</strong>se circumstances, <strong>the</strong> rapid spurt in demandand production that began in mid-1965 could not fail to affect prices.The sharp rise in demand for defense products and capital goods imposedspecial pressures on <strong>the</strong> metals and machinery industries. In somebranches <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se industries, <strong>the</strong> limits <strong>of</strong> efficient utilization were surpassed,and, in a few, output was close to absolute limitations on capacity.Even where productive resources were not fully used, it was <strong>of</strong>ten difficultto adjust production rapidly enough to keep pace with soaring demands.Time is needed, even when <strong>the</strong>re are no special problems affecting supply,to increase <strong>the</strong> output <strong>of</strong> farm products and <strong>of</strong> industrial raw materials,especially metals. It takes time to hire workers, activate additional machines,or increase <strong>the</strong> rate at which purchased supplies are delivered. In <strong>the</strong>second half <strong>of</strong> 1965 and in early 1966, <strong>the</strong> expansion <strong>of</strong> demand for manyproducts and services was pushing against <strong>the</strong>se speed limits on <strong>the</strong> expansion<strong>of</strong> output. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> demand was less balanced thanpreviously, so that pressure points multiplied. For some products andservices, production could keep up with demand only at somewhat highercosts—using standby, semi-obsolete equipment, paying overtime rates,mining lower grade ores, and so on.There were also imbalances in labor markets which created increasingdifficulties as unemployment declined. Workers in low-paid occupationscould not be retained without substantial upward adjustments <strong>of</strong> wagescales. Moreover, reduced unemployment streng<strong>the</strong>ned <strong>the</strong> bargainingposition <strong>of</strong> unions and weakened that <strong>of</strong> employers. Wages generally beganto rise faster at a time when productivity gains were slowing down. Prices<strong>of</strong> services <strong>of</strong> all kinds continued to rise, and at an accelerated rate, as wagesin many service occupations were increased substantially.The broad upswing in prices must <strong>the</strong>refore be explained in terms <strong>of</strong> acomplex interaction between a general increase in <strong>the</strong> pressure on productiveresources and special factors impinging on a limited range <strong>of</strong> product andlabor markets. Had <strong>the</strong> increase in demand been slower and more evenly73


alanced, <strong>the</strong> rise in <strong>the</strong> price level would certainly have been less, althoughsome increase would still have occurred. Farm products and raw materialswould surely have risen in any event, given <strong>the</strong> supply problems at home andabroad. Wage adjustments for low-paid occupations would still have beennecessary, though <strong>the</strong>y could have been more gradual.Although <strong>the</strong> pressures that developed in early 1966 have now abated somewhat,<strong>the</strong>y have left <strong>the</strong>ir mark on <strong>the</strong> structure <strong>of</strong> costs and prices. Prices<strong>of</strong> most farm products and <strong>of</strong> many industrial raw materials move more orless freely in both directions. The same is true, though to a lesser degree, <strong>of</strong>many products at early stages <strong>of</strong> fabrication. But it is unlikely that past priceincreases in most o<strong>the</strong>r parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy will be reversed so long as <strong>the</strong>economy remains strong. Moreover, price advances for such items asmetals and industrial equipment tend to fan out and become built into <strong>the</strong>structure <strong>of</strong> industrial costs. And even temporary increases in farm and foodprices, through <strong>the</strong>ir impact on consumer prices, materially affect <strong>the</strong> pattern<strong>of</strong> wage negotiations. The resulting higher wage settlements also tend to bepermanently built into <strong>the</strong> cost structure.Consequently, <strong>the</strong> return to price stability can only be gradual. However,as 1966 drew to a close, <strong>the</strong>re were signs <strong>of</strong> progress. Prices <strong>of</strong> farm productsand some raw materials had leveled <strong>of</strong>f. Thanks to <strong>the</strong> enormous strengthand adaptability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy and <strong>the</strong> skill and ingenuity <strong>of</strong> workers andmanagements, many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> industrial pressure points had been alleviated.With <strong>the</strong> slower pace <strong>of</strong> growth in <strong>the</strong> second half <strong>of</strong> 1966, much <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> necessaryadaptation was accomplished. More <strong>of</strong> it will be accomplished in 1967.THE RECENT PRICE RECORDThe year 1965 marked <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> a long period <strong>of</strong> price stability (Charts6 and 7). After having remained virtually constant since 1958, <strong>the</strong> wholesaleprice index rose by 3.4 percent during 1965 (i.e., December 1964 toDecember 1965) and 1.7 percent during 1966. Consumer prices increased by2.0 percent during 1965 and by 3.3 percent during 1966.Between December 1964 and September 1966, <strong>the</strong> wholesale price indexwas dominated by a rise <strong>of</strong> 14/ 2 percent in <strong>the</strong> average price <strong>of</strong> farmproducts, foods, and feeds (Table 6). This group <strong>of</strong> products accountedfor over 60 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total increase in <strong>the</strong> index over this period. In<strong>the</strong> fourth quarter <strong>of</strong> 1966, wholesale prices <strong>of</strong> farm products and foodsdropped sharply and by <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year were only 1 percent higher thanat <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> 1965. Prices <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r commodities included in <strong>the</strong> wholesaleprice index increased by 1.8 percent during 1966 (Table 7). Because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>strong demand for investment goods, <strong>the</strong> largest price increases came in <strong>the</strong>machinery producing sector, though prices <strong>of</strong> metals and metal productsalso rose appreciably.74


Chart 6Wholesale Prices1957-59=10010095FARM PRODUCTS9011 HI I I I 11 I 11 11 I I I M I I I 11 I I I 111 11 I 1111 II I I 11 I I 11 I 11 11 I I I 11 M I I 11 11 I1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966J/COMMODITIES OTHER THAN FARM PRODUCTS AND PROCESSED FOODS.SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF LABOR.TABLE 6.—Changes in wholesale and consumer prices,1964-66GroupDecember1964 toDecember1965Percentage changeDecember1965 toSeptember1966September1966 toDecember1966December1965 toDecember1966Wholesale prices:All commodities.3.42.6-0.81.7Farm products, processed foods, and manufacturedanimal feeds ,.Metals and metal productsNonelectrical machineryElectrical machinery and equipmentA ll o<strong>the</strong>r commodities., „.,Consumer prices:9.01.82.3.31.25.21.73.22.71.2-4.1.51.32.20)1.02.24.65.01.2All items.2.02.8.53.3All commodities1.62.4.12.5FoodO<strong>the</strong>r commoditiesServices3.5.82.74.51.23.5-.7.71.43.81.94.9i Less than .05 percent.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor and Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers.75


Chart 7Consumer Prices1957-59=100125120SERVICESCOMMODITIES LESS FOODi ii II h i m I n i n i l i ii ilii 111 h i 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 i 1 1 1 1 1 1 11961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF LABOR.From 1960 to 1964, <strong>the</strong> consumer price index rose at an average rate<strong>of</strong> 1.2 percent a year—with commodity prices rising by less than 1 percentand service prices increasing by about 2 percent a year (Table 8). Much<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> acceleration in consumer prices during 1965 was directly attributableto food prices, but, by <strong>the</strong> following year, prices <strong>of</strong> all major componentshad begun to rise more rapidly. Prices <strong>of</strong> services, especially in <strong>the</strong> medicaland financial areas, increased most and accounted for half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total risein <strong>the</strong> index during 1966. There were fur<strong>the</strong>r increases in foods and o<strong>the</strong>rnondurables, including a 3.7 percent rise in apparel prices. After decliningthrough 1965, prices <strong>of</strong> consumer durables began to rise in <strong>the</strong> secondquarter <strong>of</strong> 1966.Perhaps <strong>the</strong> most comprehensive measure <strong>of</strong> price movements is <strong>the</strong> implicitprice deflator for gross national product (GNP). Although consumerprices are its largest component, <strong>the</strong> deflator also reflects changes in <strong>the</strong>prices <strong>of</strong> structures, producers' durable equipment, exports and imports, andgovernment purchases. The over-all GNP deflator rose by 3.6 percentbetween <strong>the</strong> fourth quarter <strong>of</strong> 1965 and <strong>the</strong> fourth quarter <strong>of</strong> 1966. Overthat same period, prices <strong>of</strong> structures and <strong>of</strong> government purchases increasedmore than <strong>the</strong> average price <strong>of</strong> consumer expenditures, prices <strong>of</strong> producers'durables rose less, and prices <strong>of</strong> exports and imports remained unchanged.


TABLE 7.—Changes in wholesale prices, December 1965 to December 1966All commoditiesCommodity groupFarm products, foods, and feeds ..Farm products..-Processed foodsManufactured animal feedsO<strong>the</strong>r commoditiesTextile products and apparelHides, skins, lea<strong>the</strong>r, and lea<strong>the</strong>rproductsFuels and related products, andpower _Chemicals and allied productsRubber and rubber productsLumber and wood productsPulp, paper, and allied products...Metals and metal productsMachinery and motive products..Nonelectrical machinery __.Electrical machinery andequipmentMotive products..Furniture and o<strong>the</strong>r householddurablesNonmetallic mineral productsTobacco products and bottledbeveragesM iscellaneous products *_.Relativeimportancein index(percent) 1100.0026.1910.2413.971.9973.817.831.437.716.411.382.684.8013.0117.707.784.575.343.952.882.601.46Indexes, 1957-59 = 100December1965104.1107.6103.0109.4118.0102.9102.0114.6100.697.693.5101.9100.9106.6104.2111.996.6100.798.2101.6107.9104.21 As <strong>of</strong> December 1963.2 Preliminary.3 Less than 0.5 percent.* Excludes manufactured animal feeds.Note.—Detail will not necessarily add to totals because <strong>of</strong> rounding.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor and Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers.December1966 2105.9108.7101.8110.6132.0104.8101.9117.5102.198.295.0102.5103.0108.9107.9117.0101.4101.8100.4103.2110.1104.8TABLE 8.—Changes in consumer prices, 1960-66Percentage Contributiontochange,December total1965 to changeDecember in 19661966 2 (percent) 21.7 1001.017-1.2 -51.11111.3111.883-.12.51.5.61.6.62.162.2163.6384.6215.0111.12.21.62.0.6ItemRelativeimportanceinindex(percent) lPercentage change per year1960to1964December1964 toDecember1965December1965 toDecember1966Contributiontototalchange in1966(percent)AllitemsFoodNondurable commodities less foodDurable commodities- .. . .,Services* TotalLess rent100.022.824.618.134.529.11.21.2.7.52.02.22.03.52.0-1.02.72.93.33.82.8.74.95.51002621350481 As <strong>of</strong> December 1965.Note.—Detail will not necessarily add to totals because <strong>of</strong> rounding.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor.LABOR COMPENSATION AND LABOR COSTSCompensation <strong>of</strong> employees increased by $40 billion from 1965 to 1966,more than two-thirds <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> increase in GNP. Much <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> increase inmoney compensation represented labor's share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> added output produced240-782 0—67- 77


y added employment. Some <strong>of</strong> it represented labor's share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> addedoutput which resulted from <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> productivity. But some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>gain in employee compensation reflected increases in wage rates in excess<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> productivity. That part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> increase in labor compensationserved to increase unit labor costs and <strong>the</strong>reby to push prices up.Compensation per man-hour grew more rapidly in 1966 than in earlieryears. At <strong>the</strong> same time, productivity grew more slowly than usual. As aresult, unit labor costs in manufacturing showed <strong>the</strong> first significant rise since1960. For <strong>the</strong> private nonfarm economy, <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> increase <strong>of</strong> labor costsaccelerated.The tight labor markets generated by rising demand were mainly responsiblefor <strong>the</strong> rapid rise in hourly compensation, although collective bargainingpower was important in a few sectors.SUPPLY AND DEMAND IN THE LABOR MARKETThe accelerated growth <strong>of</strong> output that began in mid-1965 was accompaniedby record increases in employment throughout <strong>the</strong> economy. Asindicated in Chapter 1, <strong>the</strong> rising demand for workers also induced an increasein <strong>the</strong> supply, with nearly 500,000 more workers entering <strong>the</strong> laborforce in 1966 than demographic trends would have indicated. The number<strong>of</strong> workers on part-time schedules "for economic reasons" droppedsharply for <strong>the</strong> second year in a row, and <strong>the</strong> unemployment rate fell to<strong>the</strong> lowest level since 1953.Although no general labor shortage resulted, labor markets in almostevery industry, occupation, and area tightened appreciably, and shortagesappeared at a number <strong>of</strong> points. The abruptness <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> increase in demanditself strained <strong>the</strong> normal processes <strong>of</strong> adjustment, and contributed to morepressure on wages and on costs than would have occurred had <strong>the</strong> sameover-all level <strong>of</strong> employment been reached more slowly.Pattern <strong>of</strong> DemandThe gains in employment were distributed unevenly among industriesand occupations (Table 9). In many industries, <strong>the</strong> expansion sincemid-1965 simply accentuated long-run employment trends, such as <strong>the</strong>growth in trade and services and <strong>the</strong> decline in agriculture. After years <strong>of</strong>little change, manufacturing employment rose sharply, particularly in <strong>the</strong>durable-goods sector, reflecting <strong>the</strong> sharp increase in defense and capitalgoods spending (Chart 8).For <strong>the</strong> same reasons, <strong>the</strong> increase in <strong>the</strong> demand for workers in variousoccupations was also uneven. Many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> occupational labor shortages reportedduring <strong>the</strong> past 18 months were an intensification <strong>of</strong> longstandingimbalances between supply and demand—for example, for teachers, doctors,nurses, and engineers. But new shortages appeared in a number <strong>of</strong> skilledoccupations—machinists, toolmakers, modelmakers and patternmakers,aircraft mechanics, and setup operators for various metalworking ma-78


TABLE 9.—Changes in employment, by industry, 1960-66IndustryPercentage change per year1960 to 1964 1964 to 1965 1965 to 1966Nonagricultural payroll employment: TotalManufacturingDurable.__NondurableMining _Contract constructionTransportation and public utilitiesRetail tradeWholesale tradeFinance, insurance, and real estate-Service and miscellaneousGovernmentFederal.State and localAgricultural employment *1.8.7.9.4-2.81.4-.31.71.52.64.13.5.84.5-4.14.24.45.82.5—.34.32.14.44.02.14.55.21.36.4-3.75.15.87.73.3—.63.12.64.24.32.25.37.57.97.4-8.3i Labor force basis.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor.chines—which clearly resulted from <strong>the</strong> rapid expansion in durable manufacturing.Until <strong>the</strong> closing months <strong>of</strong> 1966, <strong>the</strong>re were, in addition, shortages<strong>of</strong> skilled construction labor in many parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> country.Meeting <strong>the</strong> Demand for LaborSome <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> increase in <strong>the</strong> demand for labor could be easily met by hiringworkers previously unemployed. For <strong>the</strong> reasons set forth in Chapter 3,however, <strong>the</strong> pattern <strong>of</strong> skills and residence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> unemployed did not fullymatch <strong>the</strong> pattern <strong>of</strong> hiring needs. Employers <strong>of</strong>ten were forced to makeo<strong>the</strong>r adjustments. They recruited at longer distances than before—in somecases even abroad; searched <strong>the</strong>ir rolls for workers who could be upgraded;redesigned jobs and even altered production methods to make better use <strong>of</strong>available workers. Hiring standards were lowered, and training programsfor both new and previously employed workers were expanded. Particularlyin manufacturing, employers leng<strong>the</strong>ned <strong>the</strong> workweek to meet <strong>the</strong>ir productionschedules.But such adjustments become increasingly costly <strong>the</strong> fur<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y arepushed. Moreover, for highly skilled occupations—at <strong>the</strong> extreme, pr<strong>of</strong>essionalworkers—several years are needed to increase <strong>the</strong> supply. Employers<strong>the</strong>refore were willing to increase what <strong>the</strong>y would pay for a worker whoalready met <strong>the</strong>ir preferred specifications. The result was a bidding up <strong>of</strong>wages for scarce skills and a rapid rise in quit rates.Competitive market pressures also extended to many low-paid types <strong>of</strong>labor. Many farm laborers, unskilled or semiskilled service workers, andfactory workers in <strong>the</strong> low-wage industries were attracted by <strong>the</strong> jobs openingup in higher wage industries and areas, and new entrants to <strong>the</strong> laborforce naturally preferred jobs in <strong>the</strong> high-wage sectors. Employers in lowwageindustries were thus forced to give larger wage increases than o<strong>the</strong>remployers in order to hold experienced workers and to recruit new ones.79


Chart 8Employment in Durable Goods Manufacturing1962 = 100, SEASONALLY ADJUSTED140120801401 1,,,,,,,,,,,),, ,,,1 n HI niminiinMiiiTiitmitniiittiNtiniI mutt tin1962 1964 1966 1962 1964 1966FABRICATEDMETALS/•AUTOS\ j /CONSTRUCTION• ' MATERIALS!/PRIMARY METALS80IIIII mi i ill i ii ii n nil 111 ii i III n I inn nun I in in in n1962 1964 1966 1962 1964 1966•STRIKE.VLUMBER AND WOOD PRODUCTS, AND STONE, CLAY, AND GLASS.SOURCES: DEPARTMENT OF LABOR AND BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM.8o


Collective BargainingMoreover, tight labor markets enhanced <strong>the</strong> bargaining power <strong>of</strong> organizedworkers and reduced that <strong>of</strong> employers. When prices and pr<strong>of</strong>itsare rising throughout <strong>the</strong> economy, workers expect to receive largerincreases than before. Also, workers are more willing to strike when jobshave been and are expected to remain plentiful. On <strong>the</strong> employers' side,wage increases are less vigorously opposed at a time when <strong>the</strong>y can easily berecovered in higher prices. In addition to <strong>the</strong> market forces that putpressure on wages, <strong>the</strong> rise in consumer prices associated with <strong>the</strong> strongexpansion <strong>of</strong> demand—as well as <strong>the</strong> high pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>of</strong> many employers—understandably streng<strong>the</strong>ned organized labor's demands for larger wageincreases generally.As a result <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> changed bargaining situation and <strong>of</strong> workers' moremilitant attitudes, more workers struck in 1966 than in any year since 1959.Also, <strong>the</strong> available information on mediated contracts indicates that in 1966union members voted down a higher proportion <strong>of</strong> tentative agreementsmade by <strong>the</strong>ir representatives than in o<strong>the</strong>r recent years.Only a limited number <strong>of</strong> contracts were negotiated during 1966, but<strong>the</strong>y provided for wage increases substantially higher than those obtainedin earlier years (Table 10). Moreover, <strong>the</strong> size <strong>of</strong> wage and fringe benefitgains tended to increase as <strong>the</strong> year progressed. A number <strong>of</strong> importantnegotiations in <strong>the</strong> second half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year resulted in compensation gainswell above those typical <strong>of</strong> earlier contracts.As a result <strong>of</strong> deferred wage increases and cost-<strong>of</strong>-living escalator adjustments,wages paid under existing contracts also rose. But <strong>the</strong>se wagegains were substantially lower than <strong>the</strong> increases obtained from contractsnewly negotiated in 1966. The median 1966 union wage increase (excludingfringes) in all nonconstruction contracts, new and existing, wasTABLE 10.—Wage changes in major collective bargaining situations, 1961-66 1Type <strong>of</strong> wage changeChanges in wage rates as percent <strong>of</strong> straight-timehourly earnings1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 2Median <strong>of</strong> first-year changes negotiated during specifiedyear:All industries..ManufacturingNonmanufacturing _Median adjustment effective during specified year,regardless <strong>of</strong> date <strong>of</strong> negotiation: 3All industries-ManufacturingNonmanufacturing.1 All contracts affecting 1,000 or more workers in all industries except construction, services, finance, andgovernment.2 Based on preliminary data available in early January 1967.3 Includes changes in wage rates negotiated during specified year, plus increases decided upon in earlieryears, cost-<strong>of</strong>-living escalator adjustments, and no wage changes.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor.8i2.82.43.62.72.72.62.92.44.02.82.63.53.02.53.42.92.73.23.22.03.62.72.03.53.84.03.73.43.43.44.44.25.03.33.03.4


3.3 percent, about <strong>the</strong> same as in 1965, although higher than in o<strong>the</strong>rrecent years.Construction workers obtained considerably larger increases in both wagesand fringe benefits than did o<strong>the</strong>r workers. The available informationindicates that <strong>the</strong> average annual increase in hourly compensation (wagesplus fringe benefits) in major construction settlements was over 6J/2 percentin both 1965 and 1966.CompensationThe pressures on <strong>the</strong> labor supply in areas o<strong>the</strong>r than manufacturingduring <strong>the</strong> past year resulted in a sharp acceleration in wage rates. Asshown in Table 11, <strong>the</strong> increases in average hourly earnings in <strong>the</strong> manufacturingindustries were exceeded by <strong>the</strong> gains in most o<strong>the</strong>r sectors.The substantial wage gains outside manufacturing extended through <strong>the</strong>whole spectrum <strong>of</strong> occupations though, as noted above, <strong>the</strong> intensity <strong>of</strong> wagepressures varied widely. Pr<strong>of</strong>essional and semipr<strong>of</strong>essional workers were incontinued short supply. In fact, <strong>the</strong>re was a general shortage <strong>of</strong> personswith a college education. The salary <strong>of</strong>fers made to graduating collegestudents in 1966 increased by about 6 percent, compared with an increase<strong>of</strong> 3^2 percent in 1965. There were also notable wage increases for nursesin many areas in <strong>the</strong> last half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year. At <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r end <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> spectrum,wage rates rose rapidly in low-wage service occupations; and agriculturalwages, which are generally low, rose by a spectacular 8.3 percent.For <strong>the</strong> entire private economy, average hourly compensation, includingfringe benefits, increased 6*/ 2 percent (Table 12). About 0.8 percentwas due to increased employer contributions for social insurance. Anda significant part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> increase reflected a shift <strong>of</strong> workers from <strong>the</strong> farmTABLE 11.—Changes in average hourly earnings, by industry, 1960-66IndustryPercentage change per yearManufacturing:Durable goods.._Nondurable goodsBituminous coal miningContract constructionTransportation and public utilities:Telephone communicationElectric, gas, and sanitary servicesLocal and suburban transportationWholesale tradeRetail trade 2Finance, insurance, and real estateService and miscellaneous:Hotels, tourist courts, and motelsLaundries and cleaning and dyeing plants 4Agriculture ._ _._1 Preliminary.2 Excludes eating and drinking places.3 Not available.4 Prior to January 1964, data relate to production workers.NOTE.—Data are for production workers in manufacturing and mining, for construction workers in con"tract construction, and for all nonsupervisory employees in o<strong>the</strong>r industries (except as noted).Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor and Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture.82


TABLE 12.—Changes in compensation;, productivity, and unit labor cost in <strong>the</strong>private economy since 1947Percentage change per yearItem1947to19651960to19641964to19651965to19661Total private, all persons:Average hourly compensation 2.Output per man-hourUnit labor costPrivate nonfarm, all persons:5.03.41.64.33.8.43.72.81.06.52.83.6Average hourly compensation 2Output per man-hourUnit labor costManufacturing, all employees:4.82.81.93.93.5.33.32.11.05.62.43.2Average hourly compensation 2Output per man-hourUnit labor cost5.13.51.53.84.0-.22.53.44.83.11.71 Preliminary; based on averages <strong>of</strong> quarterly data; not strictly comparable with changes for prior years.2 Wages and salaries <strong>of</strong> all employees and supplements to wages and salaries such as employer contributionsfor social insurance and for private pension, health, unemployment, and welfare funds, compensationfor injuries, pay <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> military reserve, etc. For total private and private nonfarm, also includes anestimate <strong>of</strong> wages, salaries, and supplemental payment part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> income <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> self-employed.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal ReserveSystem, and Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers.to <strong>the</strong> nonfarm sectors. Because wages are generally higher in <strong>the</strong> nonfarmsector, this shift <strong>of</strong> workers raises <strong>the</strong> average level <strong>of</strong> wages in <strong>the</strong> privateeconomy. In fact, it is <strong>the</strong> main reason why <strong>the</strong> over-all gain is so muchhigher than <strong>the</strong> gain in <strong>the</strong> nonfarm sector alone.Compensation per man-hour for manufacturing workers rose by 4.8percent in 1966—a significant increase over <strong>the</strong> 3.5 percent average annualgain from 1960 to 1965—but considerably less than <strong>the</strong> 5.7 percent gain foro<strong>the</strong>r nonfarm workers. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, much <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> acceleration in manufacturingcompensation was due to <strong>the</strong> increased employer contributionsfor social insurance, <strong>the</strong> rise in overtime work, and <strong>the</strong> relative shift <strong>of</strong>workers into <strong>the</strong> higher-wage durable manufacturing sector. In spite <strong>of</strong> someskill shortages and <strong>the</strong> rapid increase in general employment, manufacturersgenerally had less difficulty in recruiting than employers in some o<strong>the</strong>r sectors,because manufacturing wages are relatively high. Of course, <strong>the</strong> smallproportion <strong>of</strong> new union contracts in manufacturing negotiated during 1966also served to hold down wage increases.Productivity and Unit Labor CostsOutput per man-hour has shown a long-term upward trend but annualadvances in productivity <strong>of</strong>ten deviate significantly from <strong>the</strong> trend. Thetrend rate <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> productivity largely determines <strong>the</strong> long-term trendin real wage rates. And <strong>the</strong> changes in unit labor costs which result from<strong>the</strong> movements <strong>of</strong> employee compensation in relation to <strong>the</strong> movements <strong>of</strong>productivity play a major role in determining price level movements.The long-term advance in output per man-hour is attributable to severalfactors: an increase in <strong>the</strong> abilities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> average worker; additional capital


per worker; technological progress; and improved management and organization.A major element underlying <strong>the</strong> increased average quality <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>work force has been a steady gain in educational achievement. The expansion<strong>of</strong> private and Government training programs, better health, andimproved working conditions have also contributed to <strong>the</strong> efficiency <strong>of</strong>workers.Gains in labor skills have been accompanied by additions to <strong>the</strong> economy'sstock <strong>of</strong> productive capital. Business investment has continually provided<strong>the</strong> average worker with more and better machines to increase <strong>the</strong> speed,accuracy, and ease <strong>of</strong> his production. The rapid pace <strong>of</strong> technologicalprogress has been made possible through large and increasing investmentsin research and development.Over any reasonably long period <strong>of</strong> time, <strong>the</strong>se changing characteristics<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> labor force and <strong>the</strong> capital stock are <strong>the</strong> basic determinants <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>economy's total productive capacity and <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> productivity <strong>of</strong> its workers.But, in <strong>the</strong> short run, much <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> fluctuation in productivity is due tocyclical variations in business operating rates. During an expansion, asoperating rates pick up, firms utilize <strong>the</strong>ir capital and labor more efficiently.Until full capacity is reached, output can be increased with little or no increasein overhead labor (supervisors, clerical and maintenance workers,etc.). Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, since it is difficult and costly to adjust <strong>the</strong> work forcein response to each fluctuation in demand, changes in employment tend tolag somewhat behind production. For <strong>the</strong>se reasons, productivity gains aregenerally higher than average during periods <strong>of</strong> rising utilization rates.However, once output begins to press against capacity, less efficient equipmentis brought into use, less skilled labor is hired, and employment begins tocatch up with output. Productivity gains drop back to, and temporarilydrop below, <strong>the</strong>ir long-run rate <strong>of</strong> increase.The substantial, and sometimes erratic, short-run movements in productivitymake it impossible to provide a single, unambiguous estimate <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>trend in productivity. But a variety <strong>of</strong> statistical techniques has been usedto adjust as completely as possible for <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> short-run factors.The results for <strong>the</strong> private economy as a whole consistently indicate a trendrate <strong>of</strong> increase in real output per man-hour <strong>of</strong> somewhat over 3 percent ayear. The comparable trend for <strong>the</strong> private nonfarm economy is about halfa percentage point lower. Of course, <strong>the</strong> trends <strong>the</strong>mselves are likely tochange slowly over time.Because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> technological advances in agriculture, productivity gains inthat sector far exceed those in <strong>the</strong> nonfarm sector. This accounts in part for<strong>the</strong> fact that productivity grows faster in <strong>the</strong> total private economy than in <strong>the</strong>nonfarm sector alone. An even more important factor is <strong>the</strong> continuing shift<strong>of</strong> workers from farming into nonfarm occupations. Although productivityis growing faster in <strong>the</strong> farm sector, average output per man-hour isappreciably higher in <strong>the</strong> nonfarm sector. When a worker shifts from a farm8 4


to. a nonfarm occupation he generally increases his productivity and, thus,<strong>the</strong> average productivity in <strong>the</strong> private economy.From 1960 to 1965, as <strong>the</strong> economy moved toward full utilization <strong>of</strong> resources,it made more efficient use <strong>of</strong> its productive plant and overheadlabor. As a result, output per man-hour rose at a faster rate than <strong>the</strong> longtermtrend (Table 12). By 1965, however, productivity gains in some sectorsbegan to weaken despite <strong>the</strong> very rapid growth in output. After some5 years <strong>of</strong> rapid expansion, <strong>the</strong> deferred adjustments in employment beganto catch up with output. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, in some industries, productionbegan to press against capacity and firms were forced to use semi-obsoleteequipment, run extra shifts, hire untrained workers, and struggle withsupply bottlenecks.As output grew at a more moderate pace in 1966, firms continued to makeadjustments in <strong>the</strong>ir work force. Productivity gains remained somewhatbelow trend in all sectors, and <strong>the</strong>re was a fur<strong>the</strong>r slowdown in manufacturingproductivity. After showing strong gains in <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong> 1966, manufacturingproductivity remained virtually unchanged after midyear. For<strong>the</strong> year as a whole, output per man-hour increased by 3.1 percent—somewhatbelow <strong>the</strong> average annual increase in <strong>the</strong> postwar period.Unit Labor CostsBecause productivity gains between 1960 and 1964 were above normal, andcompensation gains relatively moderate, unit labor costs remained essentiallystable in that period. Then as productivity gains began to slacken in1965, unit labor costs were held to a modest increase by <strong>the</strong> slowdown in <strong>the</strong>growth <strong>of</strong> compensation per man-hour. For <strong>the</strong> entire private economy,unit labor costs in 1965 averaged only 2 percent higher than in 1961. In1966, however, tight labor markets pushed compensation up more rapidly,and <strong>the</strong>re was no surge in productivity to maintain stable costs. As a result,unit labor costs rose an average <strong>of</strong> more than 3y 2 percent in <strong>the</strong> privateeconomy and nearly 2 percent in manufacturing, <strong>the</strong> first appreciable increaseduring <strong>the</strong> entire period <strong>of</strong> expansion.Although <strong>the</strong> rise in unit labor costs in 1966 in <strong>the</strong> crucial manufacturingsector represents a serious break with <strong>the</strong> earlier record <strong>of</strong> stability, it waswell below <strong>the</strong> increase experienced in every o<strong>the</strong>r postwar expansion(Chart 9). Hourly compensation in manufacturing grew steadily and quiterapidly throughout <strong>the</strong> entire year. From <strong>the</strong> fourth quarter <strong>of</strong> 1965 to <strong>the</strong>fourth quarter <strong>of</strong> 1966, compensation per man-hour increased by nearly 6percent. Because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> uneven rates <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> output and productivity,most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rise in unit labor costs in manufacturing was concentrated in <strong>the</strong>second half <strong>of</strong> 1966. During <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong> 1966, unit labor costs rose at arate <strong>of</strong> about 2 percent, but <strong>the</strong>n accelerated to an annual rate <strong>of</strong> nearly 5percent in <strong>the</strong> second half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year. Since this sharp upturn was in parta reflection <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> very uneven pattern <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> output during <strong>the</strong> year,it should be regarded as temporary in nature.85


Chart 9Unit Labor Costs in Manufacturing Since 1948PREVIOUS PEAK = 100J/120115SEASONALLY ADJUSTEDA/ rv110 —/ ^^A / ! **^1948-54105/\\/ft/* 1953-58I) is/ W^—1957-6110095-\V/J ^* 1960-66V901 1 11 1 M I 11 11 11-12 12 24 36 48MONTHS FROM CYCLICAL TROUGH60 72P=CYCLICAL PEAK: JULY 1953, JULY 1957, AND MAY I960.•^PREVIOUS PEAKS ARE NOVEMBER 1948, JULY 1953, JULY 1957, AND MAY I960.^CYCLICAL TROUGHS ARE OCTOBER 1949, AUGUST 1954, APRIL 1958, AND FEBRUARY 1961.NOTE.-PERIODS COVERED ARE NOVEMBER 1948-AUGUST 1954, JULY 1953-APRIL 1958, JULY 1957-FEBRUARY1961, AND MAY 1960-DECEMBER 1966 (LATEST DATA AVAILABLE).SOURCES: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE AND BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM.In summary, all major sectors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy experienced higher unitlabor costs during 1966, particularly in <strong>the</strong> latter half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year. Thisupswing broke a long record <strong>of</strong> relative stability. Productivity gains, whichhad been above trend during previous years, slowed down in 1965 and 1966while <strong>the</strong> rise <strong>of</strong> compensation accelerated. The trend <strong>of</strong> prices, describedin <strong>the</strong> following sections, could not be insulated from <strong>the</strong> resulting rise inunit costs.PRICES IN MAJOR SECTORSIn view <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> critical significance <strong>of</strong> prices in <strong>the</strong> 1966 economic recordand in <strong>the</strong> outlook for 1967, a fuller review than usual <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> price situationin major sectors is called for in this Annual <strong>Report</strong>. This review concentrateson four sectors: farm and food products; raw materials; manufacturedproducts; and consumer services.86


FARM PRODUCTS AND FOODAs indicated earlier, farm prices rose sharply in 1965 and continued torise during <strong>the</strong> first three quarters <strong>of</strong> 1966. Prices declined sharply in <strong>the</strong>final quarter <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year and by December showed little change from a yearearlier. However, <strong>the</strong>y remained well above <strong>the</strong> levels <strong>of</strong> early 1965. Theseincreases were reflected at wholesale in <strong>the</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> processed foods, andat retail in <strong>the</strong> consumer price index.The rise in farm prices was due to <strong>the</strong> strong expansion <strong>of</strong> domesticand export demand, combined with only slightly increased or in some casesreduced supplies <strong>of</strong> important farm commodities. Given adequate time for<strong>the</strong> adjustment <strong>of</strong> production, America's farmers are capable <strong>of</strong> expandingtotal farm output to meet any foreseeable expansion <strong>of</strong> domestic demandand to provide substantial surpluses for export, in most instances at essentiallyconstant costs. To be sure, for some highly labor-intensive products—particularly dairy products and some fruits and vegetables—rising pricesmay be necessary to attract or hold <strong>the</strong> necessary labor services. But thisis <strong>the</strong> exception ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> rule. However, an expansion <strong>of</strong> farmoutput necessarily takes time—ranging from a few months for broilers, atleast a year for most field crops, 1 or 2 years for hogs, and even longer forcattle or tree crops. To expand production <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se commoditiesalso requires changes in Federal farm programs.Because <strong>of</strong> relatively long production cycles, supplies <strong>of</strong> some farm productsreflect past ra<strong>the</strong>r than current prices. In 1965, hog supplies weredeclining in response to <strong>the</strong> low prices <strong>of</strong> 1963 and 1964. The resulting risein livestock prices was intensified by strong consumer demand. The pricerise which began in 1965 continued into early 1966. After February suppliesbegan to expand, and by December wholesale livestock prices were 12.5percent below <strong>the</strong> unusually high levels <strong>of</strong> December 1965.Meanwhile, however, grain prices began to rise. At <strong>the</strong> beginning <strong>of</strong>1966, grain prices stood 2.2 percent above <strong>the</strong>ir levels <strong>of</strong> a year earlier.During 1965, demand had expanded sharply but so had production. In1966, strong domestic demand was supplemented by a jump in exports buttotal production was essentially unchanged from 1965 levels. Export demandwas particularly buoyant for wheat, as reduced supplies from Argentinaand Australia led to a rise in <strong>the</strong> volume <strong>of</strong> U.S. exports estimated atabout 20 percent.Prices for wheat, feed grains, and soybeans rose sharply during <strong>the</strong> latespring and summer. The rise was accentuated by speculation based onuncertain crop prospects and <strong>the</strong> strength <strong>of</strong> export demand. In <strong>the</strong>fall, harvests having proved somewhat better than had been expected, pricesfor grains and soybeans declined sharply. However, grain prices averaged12.6 percent higher for December 1966 than a year earlier.87


In contrast to both grain and livestock prices, dairy prices moved upsharply in <strong>the</strong> second half <strong>of</strong> 1966 as growing demands were matched witha decline in production. This decline in turn was related to general economicconditions as high beef prices induced farmers to cull and sell dairycows while excellent <strong>of</strong>f-farm employment opportunities encouraged somefarmers to abandon dairying altoge<strong>the</strong>r.Thus <strong>the</strong> major factors involved in rising farm product prices in 1966 were:(1) <strong>the</strong> hog production cycle which led to reduced marketings until mid-1966 when numbers shipped began to increase;(2) poor wea<strong>the</strong>r here and abroad which caused some decline in U.S. productionand increased <strong>the</strong> demand for U.S. wheat exports;(3) high cattle prices which resulted in reduction in dairy herds and goodemployment opportunities which induced farmers to leave dairying;(4) strong demand for food based on rising consumer incomes.Chart 10Farm and Food Prices1957-59 =120100115 -f'\-110 -105 -95WHOLESALE FARM PRODUCTS 1/908 5 1 I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I 1 I I I I M I I I I 1 I I I I 1 I I I I M I I 1 I I1961 1962 1963 1964 19651111111 111 111966J/FARM PRODUCTS INCLUDE DOMESTIC AND IMPORTED TEXTILE FIBERS, TOBACCO, AND SOME PRODUCENOT SUBJECT TO PROCESSING.SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF LABOR.88


Processed Foods and Foods at RetailChanges in food prices at subsequent levels <strong>of</strong> processing and distributiongenerally follow changes in <strong>the</strong> costs <strong>of</strong> raw farm products. These costs,however, account for only about 40 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> price <strong>of</strong> delivered foodswith <strong>the</strong> remainder reflecting costs <strong>of</strong> transportation, processing, distribution,and marketing. Over time <strong>the</strong>se latter costs have risen steadily reflecting, inpart, increases in labor costs and, in part, higher quality and better packaging.As a result, even when farm prices are stable, food prices, especially at retail,tend to rise.Chart 10 shows <strong>the</strong> relation between farm and processed food prices andretail food prices. As expected, changes in farm product prices are moredirectly reflected in processed food prices. Changes in retail food pricestend to lag behind farm prices and fluctuate with less amplitude.Following <strong>the</strong> decline in farm prices, processed food prices ended <strong>the</strong> yearonly slightly above <strong>the</strong> levels <strong>of</strong> December 1965. But retail prices remained3.8 percent above <strong>the</strong> level a year earlier. The spread between farm andretail food prices narrowed during 1965, but <strong>the</strong>n widened late in 1966.On <strong>the</strong> average, <strong>the</strong>re is little evidence <strong>of</strong> an increase in processing anddistribution margins. In <strong>the</strong> months ahead <strong>the</strong>re may be some fur<strong>the</strong>rdecline in retail prices, but <strong>the</strong> rising trend in intermediate costs suggeststhat a full reversal cannot be expected.RAW MATERIALSThe rise in raw materials prices which began in 1965 continued through1966, although <strong>the</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> hides, secondary copper, and s<strong>of</strong>twood lumber,which had risen rapidly during 1965 and early 1966, declined in <strong>the</strong> last half<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year. Prices rose for a wide range <strong>of</strong> mineral products, includingsulphur, nickel, vanadium, and a number <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r alloy metals. Somenonmineral raw materials used in industry—such as tobacco and wool—also rose.Over long periods, <strong>the</strong> relative price <strong>of</strong> mineral products reflects a racebetween <strong>the</strong> improvement <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> technology <strong>of</strong> discovery, mining, andrefining and <strong>the</strong> gradual deterioration in <strong>the</strong> quality <strong>of</strong> available ores.Despite <strong>the</strong> fact that use is now made <strong>of</strong> ores which would have beendiscarded 30 years ago, <strong>the</strong> average price <strong>of</strong> minerals has not generallyrisen relative to o<strong>the</strong>r commodities.In <strong>the</strong> short run, however, sharp increases in demand almost always meanhigher prices for both ores and metals. Since it takes several years to developnew mines, increased requirements can only be met from inventories, andby stepping up output from existing capacity and from an expansion <strong>of</strong>capacity which is already under way. Once <strong>the</strong>se limits are exceeded, as<strong>the</strong>y have been for many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> minerals, pressures on price become severe.Even when primary producers do not raise <strong>the</strong>ir prices, or do not raise <strong>the</strong>menough to balance <strong>the</strong> market, secondary market prices will rise. Theinitial advance is likely to be accentuated by inventory speculation. Cor-89


espondingly, a relatively small improvement in <strong>the</strong> supply and demandbalance can reverse <strong>the</strong> speculative movement and produce a sharp declinein price. These characteristics are shared by many nonmineral rawmaterials.The upward pressure on raw materials prices in 1965 and 1966 reflected<strong>the</strong> slow response <strong>of</strong> supply to a sharp increase in demand. It was accentuatedby <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> increase in demand was heavily concentrated indefense and capital goods which use large amounts <strong>of</strong> mineral raw materials.Random factors such as strikes and interruptions in foreign suppliesalways influence raw materials prices. Copper and hides were particularlyaffected by changes in foreign markets. However, in 1966 <strong>the</strong> strength <strong>of</strong>demand and <strong>the</strong> basically tight supply situation magnified <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong>fluctuations in supplies.In <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> copper, strong demand drove domestic consumption upby more than 200,000 short tons from <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong> 1965 to <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong>1966. Foreign supplies were reduced by strikes and political disturbancesin <strong>the</strong> principal producing nations. While this loss was largely <strong>of</strong>fset bysales from <strong>the</strong> government stockpile, prices in <strong>the</strong> United States were influencedby changes in <strong>the</strong> outlook for foreign supplies. The price <strong>of</strong> primarydomestic copper was not raised significantly until early 1967, but <strong>the</strong>price in <strong>the</strong> secondary market, which supplies about one-third <strong>of</strong> domesticconsumption, rose sharply to a peak <strong>of</strong> nearly $1.00 a pound early in 1966,compared with 36 cents for <strong>the</strong> primary refined metal. It <strong>the</strong>n eased to arange <strong>of</strong> 50 to 60 cents during <strong>the</strong> summer and fall.The influence <strong>of</strong> demand pressures was also clearly shown in <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong>s<strong>of</strong>twood lumber prices, which rose rapidly early in <strong>the</strong> year under <strong>the</strong>pressure <strong>of</strong> rising defense and construction demand, and <strong>the</strong>n sank as residentialconstruction declined.As indicated below, <strong>the</strong> rise in raw material prices played a significant rolein <strong>the</strong> increase in prices <strong>of</strong> manufactured products during 1966.MANUFACTURED GOODSIn contrast to some farm products and raw materials, price changes inmost manufacturing industries do not reflect an automatic balancing <strong>of</strong>supply with demand through <strong>the</strong> operation <strong>of</strong> impersonal market forces.Producers in many industries have some degree <strong>of</strong> discretion in setting prices,although <strong>the</strong> range <strong>of</strong> discretion varies with competitive conditions fromindustry to industry.Firms with considerable market power are <strong>of</strong>ten able to maintainmarkups over unit costs that are largely independent <strong>of</strong> changing marketconditions. In o<strong>the</strong>r industries, <strong>the</strong> effectiveness <strong>of</strong> market power is morelimited. When utilization rates are low, markups <strong>of</strong>ten have to be shaded.By <strong>the</strong> same token, when demand and capacity utilization rates are high,competitive pressures are weakened, presenting <strong>the</strong> opportunity to restoretemporarily depressed markups to desired levels or even to raise sights on90


what is desired. In a few industries, market power is insignificant andmarkups over cost vary widely with demand conditions.On <strong>the</strong> whole, <strong>the</strong> markup <strong>of</strong> prices over "standard costs" (based onassumed or standardized capacity utilization) appears to have been relativelystable in <strong>the</strong> past few years. Actual costs tend to decline as capacityutilization rises. The general improvement in capacity utilization between1961 and 1965 would have produced very substantial increases in pr<strong>of</strong>itmargins even if prices had been adjusted only enough to maintain a constantmarkup over costs calculated on a fixed volume. But as markets streng<strong>the</strong>ned,some prices were raised even though costs had not increased. Andsome firms failed to reduce prices even when standard costs were falling.After remaining stable from 1961 to 1964, prices <strong>of</strong> finished nonfoodmanufactures rose by 1.2 percent during 1965 and <strong>the</strong>n moved up by 2.5percent during 1966. Some part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> increase in prices was, <strong>of</strong> course,directly attributable to <strong>the</strong> rise in raw materials prices and unit labor costs.But <strong>the</strong> basic factor underlying <strong>the</strong> general price rise was <strong>the</strong> strength <strong>of</strong>demand and, in particular, <strong>the</strong> sharp increase in demand in late 1965 andearly 1966.Though demand pressures cannot be measured precisely, <strong>the</strong> relationbetween capacity utilization and <strong>the</strong> preferred rate <strong>of</strong> operation provides acrude measure. Capacity utilization in manufacturing has been increasingsince 1961 and <strong>the</strong> average rate in 1966 was exceeded only in 1951 and1953 in <strong>the</strong> postwar period. At <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> 1966, manufacturing industrieswere operating at an estimated 89 percent <strong>of</strong> capacity, compared with anaverage preferred rate <strong>of</strong> 93 percent (Table 13). The end-<strong>of</strong>-year capacityutilization was lower than <strong>the</strong> average for <strong>the</strong> year as a whole. Even so,TABLE 13.—Manufacturing capacity utilization, 1965-66IndustryOutput as percent <strong>of</strong>capacity 1December1965December1966Total manufacturing 3.9089Preferredrate(percent) 2 93Iron and steelNonferrous metalsMachinery__Electrical machineryAutos, trucks, and partsO<strong>the</strong>r transportation equipmentFabricated metals and instruments _Stone, clay, and glass.Chemicals .PapRubber..Petroleum and coal products. _Food and beveragesTextiles ....Miscellaneous manufacturing.759990OQ OV9695878684969694859990809592QQo\)84 102898083949897859685919593909993929290979398901 Data for 1965, except iron and steel, from McGraw-Hill; estimates for iron and steel for 1965 and allindustries for 1966 by Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers after consultation with McGraw-Hill.2 From McGraw-Hill survey <strong>of</strong> Business Plans for New Plants and Equipment, 1966-69, April 1966.3 Not comparable with data in Table B-35 because <strong>of</strong> differences in methods <strong>of</strong> computation.Sources: McGraw-Hill, Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System, and Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong>Advisers.


operations were close to or above preferred rates in 9 important sectors:nonferrous metals, nonelectrical machinery, electrical machinery, "o<strong>the</strong>r"transportation equipment (aerospace and railroad equipment), fabricatedmetal products and instruments, paper and pulp, rubber, petroleum andcoal products, and textiles. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, in 6 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se 9 sectors (allexcept nonferrous metals, paper, and textiles), operating rates ei<strong>the</strong>rincreased or held steady between December 1965 and December 1966.The pressure <strong>of</strong> demand for finished goods is in itself a major elementcontributing to <strong>the</strong> rise in wages and in raw materials prices. Translatedinto a demand for labor, it can create shortages which bid up wages, or atleast streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> bargaining power <strong>of</strong> unions. And, after being transmittedthrough a chain <strong>of</strong> suppliers and processors, <strong>the</strong> increased productionrequirements can pull up <strong>the</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> raw materials. Thus, byforcing up wages and raw materials prices, an increase in demand in onesector can raise production costs in o<strong>the</strong>r sectors. If aggregate demand isstrong, producers in <strong>the</strong>se latter sectors will tend to increase <strong>the</strong>ir prices tocover <strong>the</strong> higher costs. Thus, while it may at times be useful to describea price increase in terms <strong>of</strong> cost factors only or demand factors only, in generalboth elements will be present.The direct impact <strong>of</strong> materials costs is, <strong>of</strong> course, most evident forproducts requiring relatively little fabrication. For example, in 1966, copperpipe, brass fittings, and wire prices rose sharply in response toincreased copper prices. But <strong>the</strong> effect <strong>of</strong> higher costs continued to spread,though somewhat more slowly, to products at more advanced stages <strong>of</strong>fabrication. Ultimately, increased raw materials prices exercised a pervasiveinfluence on industrial prices, although <strong>the</strong>ir direct impact was notablein only a few cases. Similarly <strong>the</strong> rise in unit labor costs in manufacturingeventually influenced prices over a wide range <strong>of</strong> manufactured goods.But, without strong demand conditions, <strong>the</strong> rise in prices and costs wouldnot have spread so quickly nor, <strong>of</strong> course, been so large.Most manufacturing industries were affected to a greater or lesserdegree by all <strong>the</strong>se factors—rising unit labor and materials costs and pressureson capacity. However, in a few cases where demand pressures wereconspicuously absent, prices did not rise or actually declined. Thus prices<strong>of</strong> syn<strong>the</strong>tic fibers dropped during 1966 because capacity had outrun demandby a considerable margin.The machinery industries afford <strong>the</strong> outstanding example <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> problemsinvolved in operations at rates close to full capacity and <strong>the</strong>ir reflection in<strong>the</strong> price movements. The demand for machinery grew rapidly while outputwas limited by shortages <strong>of</strong> skilled labor and some types <strong>of</strong> equipment,in part because <strong>the</strong> machinery sector had to compete with expanding defenseproduction for labor, materials, and components.Spurred by <strong>the</strong> capital boom <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> past 5 years and <strong>the</strong> sharp rise in defensedemands, production <strong>of</strong> machinery expanded by 67 percent between1961 and 1966, an average annual growth <strong>of</strong> more than 10 percent. For92


<strong>the</strong> first time in many years both <strong>the</strong> electrical and <strong>the</strong> nonelectrical machineryindustries were operating in 1966 at about <strong>the</strong>ir preferred rates and,in each segment, order backlogs grew by about one-quarter.In <strong>the</strong> nonelectrical sector, <strong>the</strong>re appears to have been sufficient plantcapacity and manpower to meet <strong>the</strong> growing demand without much strainuntil early 1965. Then, beginning around mid-1965, some segments <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>industry, especially machine tool producers, began to report increasing difficultiesin recruiting and training skilled labor. After rising at an averageannual rate <strong>of</strong> only 1.1 percent between 1961 and 1964, prices <strong>of</strong> nonelectricalmachinery rose by 2.3 percent during 1965 and <strong>the</strong>n 4.6 percent during1966. Similar strains on capacity developed in <strong>the</strong> electrical machinery industryand prices, which had been declining for a number <strong>of</strong> years, changedlittle in 1965 and <strong>the</strong>n rose by about 5 percent during 1966.SummaryThe moderate but persistent upward trend in manufacturing pricesreflected <strong>the</strong> interaction <strong>of</strong> many factors, <strong>of</strong> which <strong>the</strong> most pervasivewas <strong>the</strong> rapid increase in demand at a time when <strong>the</strong> economy wasoperating close to capacity. The actual course <strong>of</strong> prices varied considerablyfrom industry to industry, depending upon <strong>the</strong> degree to whicheach was affected by changes in costs <strong>of</strong> materials, supplies, fuel, andlabor, <strong>the</strong> balance between demand at prevailing prices and <strong>the</strong> capacityto meet that demand without undue strain, and <strong>the</strong> extent and exercise <strong>of</strong>discretion in <strong>the</strong> pricing policies <strong>of</strong> leading concerns.On <strong>the</strong> average, <strong>the</strong> 2/ 2 percent increase in manufacturing pricesduring 1966 was probably about commensurate with <strong>the</strong> average percentageincrease in all elements <strong>of</strong> cost. This seems a reasonable inferencefrom <strong>the</strong> over-all pr<strong>of</strong>it record in manufacturing. During <strong>the</strong> first threequarters <strong>of</strong> 1966, after-tax pr<strong>of</strong>its for all manufacturing averaged 5.6 percent<strong>of</strong> sales, <strong>the</strong> same as in <strong>the</strong> first three quarters <strong>of</strong> 1965. As a percentage<strong>of</strong> equity, however, <strong>the</strong>y were higher—13.4 percent for <strong>the</strong> first three quarters<strong>of</strong> 1966 against 12.7 percent a year earlier.CONSUMER SERVICESSince 1947, <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> consumer services has risen at an average rate<strong>of</strong> about 3J/2 percent a year, more than twice as fast as for commodities atretail; between 1960 and 1964, <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> increase was a little over 2 percenta year; and in 1965 it was about 2 l / 2 percent.Between December 1965 and December 1966, <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> increase jumpedto 4.9 percent, accounting for half <strong>the</strong> total rise in <strong>the</strong> consumer price index.This acceleration reflected partly an intensification <strong>of</strong> existing long-run trendsand partly <strong>the</strong> appearance <strong>of</strong> new factors.The services included in <strong>the</strong> index are a highly diversified group, but<strong>the</strong>y can be regarded as comprising three very broad and somewhat over-240-782 0—67- 93


simplified categories: (1) rents and utility rates, (2) labor intensive services,and (3) financial charges.The behavior <strong>of</strong> prices in <strong>the</strong> first <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se categories differed little during1966 from earlier trends, and increases were relatively small (Table 14).The second group—labor intensive services—is quite heterogeneous; butin most cases <strong>the</strong> scope for significant improvements in productivity islimited, and <strong>the</strong>refore costs and prices are sensitive to changes in wage rates.This is true whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> labor involved is relatively highly skilled (as forpr<strong>of</strong>essional services, repair mechanics, barbers, and beauticians) or relativelyunskilled (as for domestic services, hotels, motels, or laundry and drycleaning).As already indicated, wage increases in <strong>the</strong> service industries acceleratedduring 1966. This was also true <strong>of</strong> fees for pr<strong>of</strong>essional services. The resultingrise in personnel costs was aggravated, in some instances, by increasesin o<strong>the</strong>r cost elements, such as commercial rents and hospital equipment.While prices for virtually all <strong>the</strong>se services had been rising for years, <strong>the</strong>advance was particularly sharp during 1966. Examples are shown inTable 15.The third category <strong>of</strong> services—financial costs—had received relativelylittle attention in <strong>the</strong> past, though property taxes had been rising slowlyand property insurance rates more rapidly. Both accelerated considerablyduring 1966, and a major new element was added: mortgage interest rates,which had remained quite stable in preceding years, rose by 12.4 percent.As shown in Table 14, <strong>the</strong>se higher financial costs accounted for overone-third <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total advance in prices <strong>of</strong> services during 1966. A largepart <strong>of</strong> this advance reflected increased mortgage costs. The fact that<strong>the</strong> increase in mortgage interest rates had such an impact on prices reflectsTABLE 14.—Changes in consumer pricesfor services during 1966All servicesType <strong>of</strong> serviceInterest and property insurance, and taxes.Public transportation and labor-intensive servicesPublic transportationMedical servicesSkilled labor services 1O<strong>the</strong>r2Rent and utilities-.RentUtilitiesAll o<strong>the</strong>r services


TABLE 15.—Changes in consumer prices for typical labor-intensive servicessince 1959Type <strong>of</strong> servicePercentage increase per year1959in1965December1965 toDecember1966Physicians' feesDaily service charges in hospitals..Men's haircutsDry cleaning.Local transit faresHousing maintenance services.2.76.42.81.6a. 2l3.07.816.57.76.C9.16.81 Data for 1959 not available; increase from December 1963 to December 1965 used.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor.<strong>the</strong> system <strong>of</strong> measurement used in constructing <strong>the</strong> index. The indexis designed to measure <strong>the</strong> change in prices associated with commitmentscurrently entered into, ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> change in <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> current expendituresrelated to commitments entered into in <strong>the</strong> current and past periods.Had weighting been based on current expenditures ra<strong>the</strong>r than commitmentsentered into during <strong>the</strong> year, <strong>the</strong> increase in <strong>the</strong> over-all consumer priceindex would have been about 0.4 percentage points less.There are o<strong>the</strong>r difficulties in measuring service prices. Changes in <strong>the</strong>quality <strong>of</strong> services are difficult to assess. This is particularly true <strong>of</strong> medicalservices because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> progress in medical techniques. It is impossible tomake a statistical correction for <strong>the</strong> changing quality <strong>of</strong> medical care, butit is clear that <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> a given standard <strong>of</strong> health care has risen less than<strong>the</strong> indexes indicate.PRICES AND THE DISTRIBUTION OF REAL INCOMEThe significance attached to price movements varies with <strong>the</strong> perspective<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> observer. A trade association usually reports a price rise for <strong>the</strong>products <strong>of</strong> its members as an improvement in prices. But <strong>the</strong> firms in ano<strong>the</strong>rindustry using those products describe <strong>the</strong> same price increase as anunfortunate rise in costs. A rise in <strong>the</strong> price <strong>of</strong> haircuts is a rise in <strong>the</strong> cost<strong>of</strong> living to most <strong>of</strong> us, but it means an increase in income to barbers. Wagesare incomes to workers but costs to employers.In 1966, wages, pr<strong>of</strong>its, and farm incomes all rose rapidly in moneyterms. But <strong>the</strong> gains in money income could not have been so large withoutprice increases. Those increases turned very large money gains into smaller,though still substantial, increases in real income.In 1966, <strong>the</strong> nominal increases in hourly compensation were unusuallylarge—4.8 percent for manufacturing employees and 5.7 percent for o<strong>the</strong>rnonfarm workers. Farm wages rose by 8.3 percent and net income perfarm by 10.3 percent. But after adjustment for price increases, hourlycompensation in <strong>the</strong> nonfarm sector increased by only 2.6 percent and netincome per farm rose by 7.0 percent. In manufacturing, real hourly com-95


pensation rose by less than 2 percent. Because some <strong>of</strong> that gain representedincreased employer contributions to social security, real hourly take-homepay for manufacturing workers increased even less for <strong>the</strong> year as a wholeand actually declined between <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> 1965 and <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> 1966.The disparity between <strong>the</strong> large nominal gains in hourly compensationand <strong>the</strong> very moderate increase in real compensation per man-hour in 1966emphasizes again <strong>the</strong> fact that more cannot be taken out <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy thanis produced. On <strong>the</strong> average, labor productivity in <strong>the</strong> private economy canbe expected to increase by somewhat over 3 percent a year. Real hourlycompensation cannot rise more rapidly than that except at <strong>the</strong> expense <strong>of</strong>o<strong>the</strong>r incomes. In conditions <strong>of</strong> strong demand and full utilization <strong>of</strong> resources,a general increase in money wages in excess <strong>of</strong> productivity growthis more likely to result in a rise in prices than in a corresponding increase inreal wages.When producers pursue pricing policies designed to increase <strong>the</strong> share<strong>of</strong> income going to pr<strong>of</strong>its or to maintain that share at excessively highlevels, this too is likely to be self-defeating. Despite sizable short-run fluctuationsdue to changing utilization rates, <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it share <strong>of</strong> income hasshown no perceptible trend over <strong>the</strong> long-run (Chart 11). When pr<strong>of</strong>itsare unusually high, <strong>the</strong>y encourage workers to demand higher wages. Bypushing up <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> living, <strong>the</strong> price increases necessary to sustain a highpr<strong>of</strong>it share provide fur<strong>the</strong>r incentive for increased wage demands.Thus, in 1966, price increases were no more successful in raising <strong>the</strong>pr<strong>of</strong>it share than nominal wage increases were in accelerating real wagegains. The share <strong>of</strong> gross pr<strong>of</strong>its in corporate gross income had been risingsteadily throughout <strong>the</strong> expansion. This was <strong>of</strong> course a normal responseto <strong>the</strong> rise in capacity utilization. The pr<strong>of</strong>it share reached a peak in <strong>the</strong>first quarter <strong>of</strong> 1966 and <strong>the</strong>n, despite rising prices, began to decline slowly.Within <strong>the</strong> manufacturing sector, <strong>the</strong> decline in pr<strong>of</strong>its after <strong>the</strong> firstquarter <strong>of</strong> 1966 resulted in a decline <strong>of</strong> 1J4 percentage points in <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>itshare <strong>of</strong> gross manufacturing income. Nonmanufacturing corporationsexperienced a similar though less pronounced decline in share.The decline in <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it share reversed <strong>the</strong> upward movement whichhad continued since 1961. That movement was, as noted earlier, primarilydue to <strong>the</strong> improvement <strong>of</strong> capacity utilization from <strong>the</strong> low levels rulingin 1961. In spite <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> small decline during 1966, <strong>the</strong> corporate pr<strong>of</strong>it shareremained substantially above <strong>the</strong> post-Korean average, though somewhatlower than in 1955.The relatively minor change in <strong>the</strong> aggregate share <strong>of</strong> labor income wasaccompanied by significant differences in <strong>the</strong> wage gains in particularsectors. In general, wages increased more rapidly in <strong>the</strong> nonmanufacturingsectors than in manufacturing. Construction workers made notable gains,as did medical workers from <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>essional level on down. O<strong>the</strong>r pr<strong>of</strong>essionals,such as teachers, enjoyed sizable increases in compensation, andtrade and service wages continued to advance relatively rapidly.96


Chart 11Shares <strong>of</strong> Gross Corporate IncomePERCENT OF GROSS CORPORATE INCOMEl/1008060COMPENSATION OF EMPLOYEES40NET INTEREST201954 1956 1958 1960 1962 1964 1966J/lNCOME ORIGINATING IN" BUSINESS PLUS CAPITAL CONSUMPTION ALLOWANCES; BASED ON SEASONALLYADJUSTED DATA.J/CORPORATE PROFITS PLUS INVENTORY VALUATION ADJUSTMENT.NOTE.-DATA RELATE TO DOMESTIC ACTIVITY OF NONFINANCIAL CORPORATIONS.SOURCES: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE AND COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS.Of course, <strong>the</strong> most dramatic income movement was <strong>the</strong> 7 percent gainin real income per farm. The relative improvement in farm income waslargely a result <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> sharp rise in prices <strong>of</strong> farm products in 1965 and early1966. By <strong>the</strong> last quarter <strong>of</strong> 1966, farm prices had begun to fall and incomeper farm declined substantially from <strong>the</strong> peak in <strong>the</strong> first quarter. However,for 1966 as a whole, real income per farm still showed a gain <strong>of</strong> more thanone-third over 1964.OUTLOOK FOR PRICESWhile forecasts <strong>of</strong> price trends are even more hazardous than o<strong>the</strong>r forms<strong>of</strong> economic prediction, <strong>the</strong>re is good ground for anticipating that 1967 willwitness progress toward greater price stability. That view is based on <strong>the</strong>expectation, reviewed in Chapter 1, that <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> real GNP in 1967will not exceed <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> productive resources.Average wholesale prices in <strong>the</strong> farm and food sector should be relativelystable, if wea<strong>the</strong>r is normal, with advances for some items approximately97


alanced by reductions for o<strong>the</strong>rs. However, retail food prices will probablycontinue to rise, although more slowly than in 1966.The sharp increase in mortgage interest rates, which significantly affected<strong>the</strong> average level <strong>of</strong> consumer service prices in 1966, should not be repeatedin 1967. Costs for medical care will continue to increase and prices <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rlabor intensive services may also rise, although less rapidly.Demand pressure on manufacturing prices should be significantly reducedin 1967. With capacity increasing by an estimated 7 percent, <strong>the</strong>re will bea slight reduction in average capacity utilization as well as a better balanceamong industries. A small decline in manufacturing capacity utilizationmay have an adverse effect on productivity in some industries, but, in o<strong>the</strong>rs,such a decline will reduce <strong>the</strong> need to use obsolete facilities. Moreover, <strong>the</strong>large amount <strong>of</strong> new capital coming into use should improve productivity.The movement <strong>of</strong> employment costs will be affected by a number <strong>of</strong> conflictingfactors. The pressure <strong>of</strong> demand on wages in unorganized labormarkets will be somewhat weaker. Although employment will grow inpace with <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> labor force, <strong>the</strong> balance between <strong>the</strong> skills indemand and those available will improve. However, <strong>the</strong>re will be continuedupward pressure on <strong>the</strong> compensation <strong>of</strong> some groups <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>essional andtechnical workers. At <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r end <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> scale, <strong>the</strong> scheduled increase inminimum wage rates will raise employment costs in some sectors.During 1966, negotiated wage settlements had only a limited influenceon <strong>the</strong> over-all movement <strong>of</strong> employment costs. In 1967, <strong>the</strong> average size <strong>of</strong>negotiated wage increases will tend to increase and <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> workersaffected will also be larger. These increases will have a significant influenceon <strong>the</strong> costs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> particular industries involved. However, only about 7million workers—less than 10 percent <strong>of</strong> all private employees—will be involvedin this year's wage negotiations. Consequently, taken by itself, <strong>the</strong>direct and immediate effect <strong>of</strong> higher union wage settlements will be relativelysmall. However, increases obtained by organized workers tend topull up <strong>the</strong> wages <strong>of</strong> unorganized workers in <strong>the</strong> same labor market. Thisprocess will broaden <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> union settlements on wages and costs in1967 and will continue to affect wage costs for a much longer time.The increase in employer contributions for social security in 1967 willbe much smaller than in 1966. That will more or less <strong>of</strong>fset o<strong>the</strong>r factorstending to push up <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> increase <strong>of</strong> hourly employment costs.Unit labor costs will doubtless continue to rise this year. But with greaterstability in <strong>the</strong> farm and food sector, and with less acute demand pressuresin product markets, <strong>the</strong> rise in <strong>the</strong> general price level in 1967 should bemore moderate than in 1966.


Chapter 3Maintaining Price Stability and ReducingUnemploymentTHE OUTPUT AND EMPLOYMENT gains <strong>of</strong> 1966 brought <strong>the</strong>U.S. unemployment rate to <strong>the</strong> lowest point since 1953. But <strong>the</strong>segains were accompanied by <strong>the</strong> fastest rise <strong>of</strong> prices since 1957. Onceagain, after years <strong>of</strong> absence, an old set <strong>of</strong> questions reappeared:(1) How far can unemployment be reduced without inflation?(2) If <strong>the</strong>re is a "trade-<strong>of</strong>f" between lower unemployment and pricestability, how do we choose between <strong>the</strong>m?(3) What ways are available to change <strong>the</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> such a trade-<strong>of</strong>f;how can we reduce unemployment fur<strong>the</strong>r and maintain reasonableprice stability?An analysis <strong>of</strong> recent U.S. experience throws some light on <strong>the</strong>se importantquestions, but it provides no simple answers.The remarkable economic record <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> years 1961-65 demonstratesclearly that, when surplus labor and plant capacity abound, fiscal andmonetary policies to expand demand can reduce unemployment substantially,and at stable prices. But, in 1966, as unemployment hovered justbelow 4 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> labor force, prices rose at a clearly unacceptablerate. As shown in Chapter 2, some <strong>of</strong> this rise can be attributed to temporaryand nonrecurring factors. Some was <strong>the</strong> result not <strong>of</strong> getting to4 percent unemployment but <strong>of</strong> getting <strong>the</strong>re too fast. There is good reasonto expect that, this year, an expansion <strong>of</strong> production which will holdunemployment at <strong>the</strong> present level will be consistent with a substantiallysmaller price advance. Never<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong> experience <strong>of</strong> 1966 clearly suggeststhat expanding demand cannot lower <strong>the</strong> unemployment rate muchbelow <strong>the</strong> present level without bringing an unacceptable rate <strong>of</strong> price increase.Under present conditions, an over-all unemployment rate closeto 4 percent appears to be associated with an approximate balance betweensupply and demand in most labor markets. A higher level <strong>of</strong> demandfor goods and services would create inflationary pressures in both productand labor markets.If <strong>the</strong> economy is now in <strong>the</strong> range <strong>of</strong> trade-<strong>of</strong>f between falling unemploymentand rising prices, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> second question above needs to befaced: how should we rank <strong>the</strong> advantages <strong>of</strong> fuller employment against<strong>the</strong> disadvantages <strong>of</strong> rising prices?99


In a meaningful sense, any involuntary unemployment is too much.Ideally, everyone who wants work should be able to find it. To tolerateany unemployment, o<strong>the</strong>r than temporary, means subjecting individuals toconcentrated hardship, both economic and psychological. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rhand, it is clear that <strong>the</strong> overwhelming majority <strong>of</strong> Americans would alsosay that any rise <strong>of</strong> prices is too much. Rising prices create hardships forthose on fixed incomes or with savings fixed in money value, and windfallsfor o<strong>the</strong>rs. Moreover, more than a very slow rise <strong>of</strong> prices can createeconomic distortions that threaten continued prosperity. And a significantrise in prices would surely worsen <strong>the</strong> U.S. balance <strong>of</strong> payments, not onlyin <strong>the</strong> short run but for some time to come. Surely, at <strong>the</strong> present juncture,when <strong>the</strong> payments balance remains in persistent deficit, inflation couldundermine <strong>the</strong> ability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> United States to carry out its objectives around<strong>the</strong> world.Faced with a desire for both lower unemployment and price stability,<strong>the</strong> third question thus becomes <strong>the</strong> really relevant one: How can <strong>the</strong>terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> trade-<strong>of</strong>f between lower unemployment and greater pricestability be altered?This chapter does not attempt to deal with all <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> answers to thisquestion; but it deals with three.First, <strong>the</strong> pattern <strong>of</strong> skills and related attributes <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> unemployed canbe more closely adapted to <strong>the</strong> pattern which employers seek; and <strong>the</strong>functioning <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> labor market can be improved so that qualified workersand suitable vacancies can be brought toge<strong>the</strong>r more expeditiously.Second, all Government policies affecting markets for goods and servicescan be directed toward <strong>the</strong> objective <strong>of</strong> achieving general price stability inan economy with sustained full employment.Third, producers and labor unions can learn to use <strong>the</strong>ir market powermore responsibly.Public policies to improve <strong>the</strong> performance <strong>of</strong> labor and product markets,and private policies <strong>of</strong> voluntary restraint in price and wage decisions, willtoge<strong>the</strong>r enable <strong>the</strong> American economy to move gradually in <strong>the</strong> comingyears toward lower unemployment with stable prices.IMPROVING U.S. LABOR MARKETSDuring each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> three recessions since 1950, unemployment rose sharply,<strong>the</strong>n returned to a rough plateau—at about 3 percent in 1952-53, 4 percentin 1955-57, and 5J/2 percent in 1959-60. There were many who readinto this record an ominous and irreversible trend toward ever higherrates <strong>of</strong> unemployment, even in "prosperity." Pr<strong>of</strong>ound structural changesin <strong>the</strong> economy during <strong>the</strong> 1950's, <strong>the</strong>y argued, had rapidly and radicallyaltered <strong>the</strong> pattern <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> demand for labor. The new pattern was notmatched within <strong>the</strong> ranks <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> labor force.This <strong>the</strong>sis found many supporters in early 1961, when, with an unemploymentrate <strong>of</strong> about 7 percent, a new national administration was deter-IOO


mining its economic targets and <strong>the</strong> means to achieve <strong>the</strong>m. Most economistsadvising <strong>the</strong> new Administration argued that an adequate increasein <strong>the</strong> total demand for goods and services could restore unemployment tomoderate levels. The advocates <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> structural change <strong>the</strong>sis agreedthat more demand for goods and services would create more job openings,but predicted that before unemployment was reduced very much, <strong>the</strong> economywould experience serious labor shortages and a resulting inflation <strong>of</strong>wages and prices.It is obvious now, if it was not obvious in 1961, that <strong>the</strong>re were <strong>the</strong>nplenty <strong>of</strong> unemployed workers available to fill almost every job that could becreated by a general expansion <strong>of</strong> demand. Labor shortages, except in afew pr<strong>of</strong>essional areas, were only a distant threat. Chapter 1 has shown how<strong>the</strong> long economic expansion that began in 1961 produced a sharp andsteady decline in unemployment. But as <strong>the</strong> unemployment rate approached4 percent in late 1965, and dipped below it in early 1966, significantlabor shortages appeared.Shortages <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>essional and subpr<strong>of</strong>essional personnel in medicine andeducation, which have existed for a number <strong>of</strong> years, continued and wereintensified. New shortages appeared in a number <strong>of</strong> highly skilled occupations,particularly in defense and capital goods industries. And <strong>the</strong>re wasa more general excess demand for workers who could fully meet employers'minimum standards for work experience and education. To be sure, employerslowered hiring standards and expanded training activities significantly,and made numerous o<strong>the</strong>r adjustments <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> kind outlined inChapter 2. But <strong>the</strong> rapid expansion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> demand for labor strained <strong>the</strong>capacity <strong>of</strong> employers to adapt <strong>the</strong>ir employment requirements to <strong>the</strong>characteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> available labor force or, through training or o<strong>the</strong>rmeans, to adapt <strong>the</strong> available labor force to <strong>the</strong> requirements <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> vacantjobs.The unemployment remaining today is not <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> same character as that<strong>of</strong> 1961. Plans for fur<strong>the</strong>r reduction <strong>of</strong> unemployment must be geared to<strong>the</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> present problem. This requires a careful examination <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> composition <strong>of</strong> today's unemployed.COMPOSITION OF THE UNEMPLOYEDUnemployment rates for almost every category <strong>of</strong> workers have beensharply reduced in recent years; yet <strong>the</strong> incidence <strong>of</strong> unemployment—byoccupations, by age, by sex, and by o<strong>the</strong>r characteristics—is still highlyuneven. By occupation, rates in 1966 varied from 7.3 percent for nonfarmlaborers to 1.3 percent for pr<strong>of</strong>essional and technical workers (Table 16).By age, unemployment rates were high for teenagers, very much loweramong workers aged 20-44, and still lower among older workers. Rates forwomen at all ages were higher than for men (Table 17). The pattern <strong>of</strong>unemployment rates by age and sex for nonwhite workers was similar tothat for white workers. But unemployment among nonwhite workers wasIOI


TABLE 16.—Unemployment rates, by major occupation groups, 1961 and 1966[Percent *]Occupation group19611966TotalWhite-collar workers:Pr<strong>of</strong>essional and technical workersManagers, <strong>of</strong>ficials, and proprietors, except farmClerical workers. _Sales workersBlue-collar workers:Craftsmen and foremenOperativesNonfarm laborersService workers:Private household workersO<strong>the</strong>r service workers __Farm workers:Farmers and farm managersFarm laborers and foremen_6.72.01.84.64.76.39.614.55.97.4.45.73.91.31.02.82.72.84.37.33.64.8.44.1i Number <strong>of</strong> unemployed in each group as percent <strong>of</strong> labor force in that group; data relate to persons 14years <strong>of</strong> age and over.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor.TABLE 17.—Unemployment, by age,sex, and color, 1966UnemploymentGroupPercentageNumber(thousands) distributionRate(percent) iAdults 45 years <strong>of</strong> age and over:Males.. _ _ _442152.3White __3711222.1Nonwhite714.2Females28610 2.7White -- __23482 2.5Nonwhite52 4.4Total_-_2,9761003.9Teenagers (14-19 years <strong>of</strong> age):Males5031711.2White39413 9.9Nonwhite109421.2Females..___ 4351513.0White33011 11.0Nonwhite_.104331.1Adults 20-44 years <strong>of</strong> age:Males 678232.6White5301852.3Nonwhite _ _ _1485.3Females632214.6White4671664.0Nonwhite__.,__ _ 1657.81 Number <strong>of</strong> unemployed in each group as percent <strong>of</strong> labor force in that group.NOTE.—Detail will not necessarily add to totals because <strong>of</strong> rounding.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor.IO2


more than twice as high as among white workers, ranging between 1 ^ and 3times as high in each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> various age and sex groups. As total unemploymenthas fluctuated, <strong>the</strong>se relative patterns <strong>of</strong> unemployment rates havebeen fairly stable (Chart 12).Unemployment averaged 3.5 million persons in 1965 (<strong>the</strong> latest yearfor which <strong>the</strong> following data are available), but more than 12.3 million, or14 percent <strong>of</strong> all persons who were in <strong>the</strong> labor force at some time during<strong>the</strong> year experienced some unemployment. Most <strong>of</strong> those unemployed wereout <strong>of</strong> work only once during <strong>the</strong> year, and <strong>the</strong>n only briefly. But 16 percenthad two spells <strong>of</strong> unemployment, and nearly 20 percent had three ormore.Much <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> unemployment during <strong>the</strong> years 1957 through 1965 was <strong>the</strong>result <strong>of</strong> an inadequate total demand for goods and services. This issometimes referred to as "cyclical" unemployment; but since a large part<strong>of</strong> it persisted through <strong>the</strong> post-recession expansions <strong>of</strong> 1958-60 and 1961-65,<strong>the</strong> cyclical label is clearly unsatisfactory.With <strong>the</strong> virtual elimination <strong>of</strong> cyclical unemployment in 1966, most<strong>of</strong> that which remains can usefully be described as ei<strong>the</strong>r "frictional" or"structural." But <strong>the</strong>se terms are not entirely precise; <strong>of</strong>ten, a particularChart 12Unemployment RatesPERCENT 31302010MENI I I I I I I1956 1958 1960 1962 1964 1966* PERCENT OF CIVILIAN LABOR FORCE IN EACH GROUP.SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF LABOR.IO3


worker who is without a job cannot easily be classified as ei<strong>the</strong>r frictionallyor structurally unemployed. Moreover, whenever <strong>the</strong>re is also unemploymentthat is due to inadequate demand, it becomes impossible in many casesto say which particular workers are unemployed for frictional, structural, orcyclical reasons. It is obvious, for instance, that not all unskilled workersor older workers who were unemployed in 1961 were structurally unemployed;very large numbers <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m found jobs in <strong>the</strong> subsequent period <strong>of</strong>expansion. The reason why many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> unskilled workers or older workerswho were without jobs in 1966 could be called structurally unemployed is notthat <strong>the</strong>y were necessarily different from those millions <strong>of</strong> unskilled or olderworkers who were at work. Ra<strong>the</strong>r, in many cases more unskilled workerscould be hired only if employers could readily find <strong>the</strong> necessary complement<strong>of</strong> skilled workers who were in relatively short supply. There isno need for construction laborers if construction is held up by <strong>the</strong> absence<strong>of</strong> bricklayers or pipefitters. But a great many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> "structurally unemployed"have characteristics that make employers reluctant to hire <strong>the</strong>mexcept under conditions <strong>of</strong> ra<strong>the</strong>r severe labor shortage."FRICTIONAL" UNEMPLOYMENTEven in an economy characterized by steady high-level employment, someinvoluntary unemployment is bound to occur. New workers need time t<strong>of</strong>ind jobs even when jobs are available. Continuous changes in <strong>the</strong> composition<strong>of</strong> demand cause fluctuations in <strong>the</strong> output and manpower requirements<strong>of</strong> individual plants though <strong>the</strong> total level <strong>of</strong> demand in <strong>the</strong> economymay be growing steadily. There are seasonal variations in activity inmany sectors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy, such as construction, recreation, and agriculture.The secondary effects <strong>of</strong> strikes in some plants or industries maycause workers in o<strong>the</strong>r plants or industries to be laid <strong>of</strong>f temporarily.Whe<strong>the</strong>r unemployment from <strong>the</strong>se causes is called—or in fact is—frictional,depends on whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> workers involved have <strong>the</strong> skills and o<strong>the</strong>rcharacteristics to qualify for available jobs and on <strong>the</strong> availability <strong>of</strong> jobs.In 1966, more than 40 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> unemployment among men over25, nearly 56 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> unemployment among women over 25, and 82percent <strong>of</strong> unemployment among teenagers was associated with ei<strong>the</strong>r entry,reentry, or voluntary job change. Workers entering <strong>the</strong> labor force foundjobs more quickly than in 1965; but <strong>the</strong> number entering was also considerablygreater. As a result, unemployment associated with <strong>the</strong>se causeschanged little. Since unemployment from o<strong>the</strong>r causes declined, <strong>the</strong> proportion<strong>of</strong> total unemployment associated with entry and job changeincreased during 1966.In most cases, unemployment due to entry or reentry is <strong>of</strong> short duration;but a small percentage <strong>of</strong> new entrants may not be able to find <strong>the</strong>ir firstjobs for some months. They account for a substantial fraction <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> totalunemployment associated with entry.104


The primary reason why unemployment rates are consistently higher forteenagers and women than for male adults is <strong>the</strong> higher proportion <strong>of</strong> teenagersand women who are new entrants or reentrants into <strong>the</strong> labor force.Moreover, <strong>the</strong> voluntary turnover rate <strong>of</strong> young workers is particularly high,as <strong>the</strong>y <strong>of</strong>ten try several jobs in search <strong>of</strong> one <strong>the</strong>y like.The rising trend <strong>of</strong> unemployment rates among teenagers relative to o<strong>the</strong>rworkers in recent years reflects <strong>the</strong> fur<strong>the</strong>r fact that <strong>the</strong> size <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> teenagelabor force—which had been stable or contracting in <strong>the</strong> early postwarperiod—more recently has been sharply expanding. New entrants obviouslymake up a larger proportion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> teenage labor force when that force israpidly growing. Thus, in 1953, when <strong>the</strong> over-all unemployment rate was2.9 percent, teenage unemployment averaged 7.1 percent. At that time, <strong>the</strong>total teenage labor force was actually declining slightly. The higher teenageunemployment rate <strong>of</strong> 12 percent in 1966 largely reflected <strong>the</strong> fact that<strong>the</strong> teenage labor force is now increasing rapidly—by 11 percent in 1966.The rising proportion <strong>of</strong> women in <strong>the</strong> labor force also tends to increase<strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> unemployment associated with entry, reentry, and departure.A ra<strong>the</strong>r high rate <strong>of</strong> voluntary turnover is an important characteristic<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> restless, mobile American worker, compared with workers in mosto<strong>the</strong>r countries. Moreover, voluntary turnover rises as labor markets tighten,and workers feel more secure in <strong>the</strong>ir ability to find o<strong>the</strong>r jobs. Of course,not all voluntary job changes involve any intervening unemployment. Whilefrictional unemployment associated with causes o<strong>the</strong>r than entry and turnoveris substantial, no useful data regarding its extent are available.Frictional unemployment could be reduced somewhat if <strong>the</strong> demand forlabor were to continue to expand more rapidly than <strong>the</strong> normal growth <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> labor force. Workers in seasonal occupations would find it easier toobtain o<strong>the</strong>r jobs in <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>of</strong>f season. New entrants to <strong>the</strong> labor force wouldfind first jobs somewhat more quickly. There would be fewer temporarylay<strong>of</strong>fs to "adjust inventories." Such a reduction <strong>of</strong> frictional unemploymentwould not only make jobs easier to find, but it would also make jobvacancies more widespread. Frictional unemployment might be reduced;but only by a fur<strong>the</strong>r tightening <strong>of</strong> labor markets, creating greater upwardpressure on wages and prices.It is impossible to eliminate frictional unemployment completely andundesirable to try. The efficient allocation <strong>of</strong> labor depends on <strong>the</strong> movement<strong>of</strong> experienced workers to better jobs. The frequent entry and reentry<strong>of</strong> women into <strong>the</strong> labor force in response to improving job opportunitiesis an important source <strong>of</strong> flexibility. The interval between leavingschool and <strong>the</strong> first job could be reduced, although it cannot be entirelyclosed in all cases. The freedom to change jobs—if only for <strong>the</strong> sake <strong>of</strong>variety—is a right that Americans cherish. The seasonally <strong>of</strong> many types<strong>of</strong> activity can be reduced, but not eliminated. And <strong>the</strong> rapid pace <strong>of</strong>technological change that contributes to <strong>the</strong> rapid advance <strong>of</strong> living standardsalso requires some involuntary job changes. Yet <strong>the</strong>re are ways to105


educe frictional unemployment without increasing <strong>the</strong> tightness <strong>of</strong> job markets.IMPROVING THE OPERATION OF LABOR MARKETSUnemployed workers <strong>of</strong>ten fail to find vacancies which <strong>the</strong>y are capable<strong>of</strong> filling, because <strong>the</strong>y are unaware <strong>of</strong> such vacancies, because <strong>the</strong>y are in<strong>the</strong> wrong location, or because <strong>of</strong> artificial job entrance requirements.The U.S. Employment Service and its affiliated State employment servicesperform an important function by bringing jobs and workers toge<strong>the</strong>r,and thus reducing frictional unemployment. During recent years, <strong>the</strong>yhave sought to improve <strong>the</strong>ir effectiveness in matching jobs and men throughimproving <strong>the</strong> quantity and quality <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir job market information (including<strong>the</strong> experimental development <strong>of</strong> job vacancy data) and throughmore effective dissemination <strong>of</strong> this information to job seekers, employers,schools, and community groups; through working more closely with employersto alleviate occupational shortages and to meet defense manpowerneeds; and through developing an experimental automated systemfor matching available jobs with characteristics <strong>of</strong> applicants in both interareaand interstate recruitment. They have also sought to improve <strong>the</strong>irservice to disadvantaged workers through cooperating with CommunityAction agencies and o<strong>the</strong>r community groups, through sending mobile teamsto rural and smaller urban areas, through making greater efforts to reach<strong>the</strong> disadvantaged in slum sections <strong>of</strong> metropolitan areas and through YouthOpportunity Centers. A detailed report on methods for improving <strong>the</strong>effectiveness <strong>of</strong> public employment services has recently been made by apublic Task Force on <strong>the</strong> Employment Service. Legislation will be proposedincorporating many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> recommendations <strong>of</strong> this report.General expansion in <strong>the</strong> economy has reduced unemployment remarkablyin many areas formerly considered to be "depressed areas." Never<strong>the</strong>less,a few areas <strong>of</strong> regional depression or underdevelopment remain. Theactivities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce under <strong>the</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> DevelopmentAct and <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Appalachian Regional Commission established in1965 are continuing to assist such areas in developing new industries byproviding loans, public works, technical assistance, and manpower training.Whenever <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> general prosperity and <strong>of</strong> new development programscannot promise adequate local employment for all workers, migration<strong>of</strong> workers is clearly called for. Often those who should migrate inorder to find jobs ei<strong>the</strong>r fail to do so—sometimes because <strong>of</strong> financial inability—ormove with inadequate knowledge <strong>of</strong> where jobs are availablefor which <strong>the</strong>y might be suited. The Department <strong>of</strong> Labor has operatedan experimental program <strong>of</strong> relocation allowances and relocation counseling,<strong>the</strong> results <strong>of</strong> which need to be thoroughly evaluated in order to determinehow relocation assistance might usefully become an expanded element inU.S. manpower policies. Relocation programs appear to have been highlysuccessful in reducing frictional unemployment in several o<strong>the</strong>r countries.106


"STRUCTURAL" UNEMPLOYMENTDuring 1965, nearly 3.5 million workers were unemployed for more than15 weeks during <strong>the</strong> year, and about 1.2 million <strong>of</strong> those workers were unemployedfor 27 weeks or more but, <strong>of</strong> course, not all at <strong>the</strong> same time.These 3.5 million workers accounted for nearly two-thirds <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total number<strong>of</strong> man weeks <strong>of</strong> unemployment. On <strong>the</strong> basis <strong>of</strong> monthly data on <strong>the</strong>long-term unemployed, it can be estimated that <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> workers wholost 15 or more weeks <strong>of</strong> work during 1966 fell to about 2.5 million. Ofthat number about 1.3 million workers were unemployed for more than 15consecutive weeks, over twice <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> persons appearing in <strong>the</strong>monthly statistics <strong>of</strong> long-term unemployment. An additional 1.2 millionworkers lost at least 15 weeks <strong>of</strong> work in several spells <strong>of</strong> joblessness. Workersexperiencing severe unemployment are found most frequently amongfarm and nonfarm laborers, operatives, and service workers—generally, <strong>the</strong>least skilled. By industries, long-term unemployment is most heavily concentratedin agriculture, construction, mining, entertainment and recreation,food and kindred products manufacturing, and private households.Several <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se sectors have a strongly seasonal character.Classified by <strong>the</strong>ir demographic characteristics, those most exposed tosevere unemployment were youths out <strong>of</strong> school, nonwhite workers, or olderworkers. Each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se groups suffers from some special disadvantage.Over-all unemployment rates for older men are relatively low, because<strong>the</strong>y do not leave jobs readily and seniority <strong>of</strong>ten protects <strong>the</strong>m from lay<strong>of</strong>for dismissal. But older workers who do become unemployed because <strong>of</strong>plant closings or relocations or technological change <strong>of</strong>ten have severe problemsin finding new jobs. They are less mobile than new workers; it is<strong>of</strong>ten more difficult for <strong>the</strong>m to learn new skills; and <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> trainingis higher per year <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir remaining working career. Employers may alsohave to assume higher pension costs when <strong>the</strong>y employ older workers.Nonwhite workers suffer from discrimination, as well as from <strong>the</strong> pooreducation and lack <strong>of</strong> skills which are in large measure <strong>the</strong> result <strong>of</strong> pastdiscrimination. Some ghetto areas are located far from areas <strong>of</strong> expandingemployment in <strong>the</strong> same metropolitan complex, and transportation facilitiesare <strong>of</strong>ten inadequate. Nonwhite teenagers make up a large proportion<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> out-<strong>of</strong>-school youths unemployed for long periods. They suffer <strong>the</strong>disadvantages <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r nonwhite workers. Like all teenagers in this group,many cannot get jobs because <strong>the</strong>y have little or no work experience, andcannot get experience because <strong>the</strong>y cannot get jobs.O<strong>the</strong>r concentrations <strong>of</strong> long-term unemployment are found in depressedareas, or areas where job opportunities for workers with particular skills areno longer available.Many individuals with serious unemployment problems suffer personaldisadvantages which make it difficult for <strong>the</strong>m to get or hold jobs even ina tight labor market. Special studies <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> unemployed in ghetto areasindicate that many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> long-term unemployed are functionally illiterate.107


Many fail entrance tests for military service. Poor health and physicaldefects are common. Some are mentally retarded or physically handicapped.Some suffer from emotional instability. O<strong>the</strong>rs have prisonrecords. Many have poor work habits, and lack motivation and discipline.They lose jobs because <strong>of</strong> absenteeism, tardiness, and inability to followinstructions. Some are younger workers who are unwilling to take lowpaying, "dead-end" jobs, but lack <strong>the</strong> patience, discipline, or opportunityto acquire training for better ones.While an expansion in <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> jobs available would surely causesome reduction in unemployment among <strong>the</strong>se workers, it is clear that many<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m will not be steadily employed—except under conditions <strong>of</strong> severeand general labor shortage—until a heavy investment has been made inimproving <strong>the</strong>ir skills and education and in helping <strong>the</strong>m to solve <strong>the</strong>irpersonal problems.A concentrated attack on <strong>the</strong> causes <strong>of</strong> "structural" unemployment is obviouslyessential if we are to move toward continually lower unemploymentwhile maintaining reasonable stability <strong>of</strong> prices. However, this statement<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> need for attacking <strong>the</strong>se social problems is obviously far too narrow.We need to attack discrimination not only because it stands in <strong>the</strong> way <strong>of</strong>fuller utilization <strong>of</strong> our economic potential, but because it is morally wrong.We would need to assist <strong>the</strong> handicapped and <strong>the</strong> disadvantaged—even ifwe were not able to lower <strong>the</strong> over-all unemployment rate—in order tomake it possible for <strong>the</strong>m to compete on more equal terms for whatever jobsare available. We need to open <strong>the</strong> doors <strong>of</strong> opportunity for individual developmentand self-fulfillment through useful employment .even if we shouldconclude that, on purely economic grounds, it would be cheaper merely toprovide guaranteed incomes regardless <strong>of</strong> contribution to production.FEDERAL MANPOWER TRAININGIn recent years, <strong>the</strong> Federal Government has launched a major effortto provide training and retraining designed to develop <strong>the</strong> large reservoir<strong>of</strong> unused or underutilized talent in <strong>the</strong> labor force, with emphasis on <strong>the</strong>disadvantaged. These include <strong>the</strong> Manpower Development and TrainingAct (MDTA), Job Corps, Neighborhood Youth Corps, Work Experience,<strong>the</strong> Office <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Opportunity (OEO) Adult Work Program, and <strong>the</strong>OEO Special Impact Program for retraining and employing residents<strong>of</strong> blighted urban areas. The distribution <strong>of</strong> trainees for <strong>the</strong> last and <strong>the</strong>current fiscalyear is shown in Table 18.Under <strong>the</strong> MDTA program, 175,000 persons were enrolled in training forproductive employment in fiscal 1966; and from its inception in 1962through December 1966, 613,000 persons were enrolled in training for1,300 occupations. The typical MDTA trainee was a white male, highschool graduate. Only one-third <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> trainees were from <strong>the</strong> disadvantagedgroups that form <strong>the</strong> bulk <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> hard-core unemployed. Experienceunder <strong>the</strong> Act has led to an altered program emphasis which will ex-108


TABLE 18.—Training opportunities, fiscal years 1966-67ProgramManpower Development and Training Act Program _Institutional trainingOn-<strong>the</strong>-job training and o<strong>the</strong>r .Job CorpsNeighborhood Youth Corps: 2In-schoolOut-<strong>of</strong>-schoolSummerWork experienceAdult work program.Special impactNumber <strong>of</strong> trainees(thousands)196627316011310106552096119671250125125311256016546251 Estimates.2 Each position may be occupied by more than one person in <strong>the</strong> course <strong>of</strong> a training period, since trainees<strong>of</strong>ten do not occupy positions for <strong>the</strong> full period.Source: Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Budget.pand <strong>the</strong> highly succesful on-<strong>the</strong>-job training component and raise to twothirds<strong>the</strong> proportion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> disadvantaged in MDTA programs—particularlyolder workers displaced by technological change, persons in correctionalinstitutions, handicapped workers, <strong>the</strong> paroled, <strong>the</strong> illiterate, and <strong>the</strong>young. Special assistance will be given for intensive on-<strong>the</strong>-job trainingto prepare disadvantaged persons for jobs with private firms.The remaining Federal programs are wholly aimed at <strong>the</strong> disadvantaged.In 1966, <strong>the</strong> Neighborhood Youth Corps program reached 220,000 needystudents, who received an average <strong>of</strong> $500 <strong>of</strong> aid fronr iri-school and summerprograms which helped <strong>the</strong>m to continue in school, and 100,000 youthsno longer in school, who received an average <strong>of</strong> 7 months <strong>of</strong> training. Sinceits inception, <strong>the</strong> Job Corps has provided training and work experience for61,500 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> most disadvantaged youths. When first enrolled, more than50 percent <strong>of</strong> Job Corps enrolles fail to read at <strong>the</strong> 5th grade level, and 30percent cannot read a simple sentence. Despite this handicap, <strong>the</strong> retentionrate for <strong>the</strong> Job Corps is superior to that <strong>of</strong> vocational training programsnationally. However, <strong>the</strong> difficulty <strong>of</strong> reaching <strong>the</strong>se hard-core unemployedyouth and <strong>the</strong> need for residential training facilities result in highunit costs.O<strong>the</strong>r Training ProgramsIn addition to <strong>the</strong>se programs which emphasize immediate impact, <strong>the</strong>longer-range objective <strong>of</strong> continuing improvement in available skills is animportant component <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r Federal programs. This objective underliesFederal support <strong>of</strong> education ranging from <strong>the</strong> basic Elementary and SecondaryEducation Act <strong>of</strong> 1965 and <strong>the</strong> Higher Education Act <strong>of</strong> 1965 to<strong>the</strong> more specific Allied Health Pr<strong>of</strong>essions Personnel Training Act <strong>of</strong>1966.240-782 0—67-IO9


About 5.8 million persons were enrolled in vocational education programsin 1966. Although some reorientation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se programs has occurred, <strong>the</strong>iroccupational distribution continues to stress traditional areas <strong>of</strong> homeeconomics and agriculture, along with <strong>of</strong>fice and industrial occupations. Itis essential that vocational training programs be more rapidly transformed toconform with <strong>the</strong> changing pattern <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy and <strong>of</strong> its laborrequirements. A comprehensive evaluation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> role and effectiveness <strong>of</strong>vocational education is a necessity for developing sound national manpowerpolicies. The establishment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Advisory Council on Vocational Educationto appraise <strong>the</strong> results <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Vocational Training Act <strong>of</strong> 1963 is astep in <strong>the</strong> right direction. Its evaluation and recommendations must beplaced in <strong>the</strong> perspective <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> future manpower needs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Nation and<strong>the</strong> various alternative methods <strong>of</strong> meeting <strong>the</strong>se needs.The apprenticeship programs operated in cooperation with <strong>the</strong> FederalGovernment are more directly focused on providing <strong>the</strong> skills needed byindustry. In <strong>the</strong> past year, 25,000 workers completed apprenticeship programs,primarily in <strong>the</strong> construction trades. There are currently 237,000federally registered apprentices. The completion rate in <strong>the</strong>se programswas 60 percent, but many dropouts found o<strong>the</strong>r work or returned to school.The rapid growth in <strong>the</strong> demand for skilled craftsmen in factories andconstruction requires an expansion <strong>of</strong> apprentice training. However, <strong>the</strong>reis some question whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> expanding needs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> construction industrycan better be met by traditional apprenticeship training aimed at <strong>the</strong> production<strong>of</strong> fully qualified craftsmen ra<strong>the</strong>r than by training specialistswith a more limited range <strong>of</strong> skills. A great deal needs to be done toincrease <strong>the</strong> enrollment <strong>of</strong> minority groups in apprenticeship programs.Encouraging signs have been observed in certain major nor<strong>the</strong>rn cities, particularlyin <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> cooperation with trade unions and civil rightsgroups in New York City, Cleveland, and Chicago, but <strong>the</strong>y are only abeginning.Issues in Manpower TrainingThe large and rapid expansion <strong>of</strong> Federal training activities obviouslyresponds to a major need, and it is clear that such programs will be andshould be fur<strong>the</strong>r expanded in <strong>the</strong> years to come. In recognition <strong>of</strong> thisfact, it is important that a number <strong>of</strong> issues be clearly faced.(1) Manpower training has several interrelated objectives. Differentkinds <strong>of</strong> training programs are needed for pursuing each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se objectives,and decisions need to be made as to <strong>the</strong> relative emphasis to be placed oneach. Broadly speaking, training is needed for three purposes. First,training is needed for <strong>the</strong> disadvantaged who are barely, if at all, employablewithout it. Second, training or retraining is needed for workers whosuffer no special deprivation or disadvantage o<strong>the</strong>r than that <strong>the</strong>y lack <strong>the</strong>IIO


specific skills now in demand by employers. This is a need which will continue—andincrease—in an economy marked by rapid technologicaladvance. Third, training is needed to help break immediate skill bottlenecks.To <strong>the</strong> extent that expanded employment <strong>of</strong> unskilled workersis held back by shortages <strong>of</strong> special skills, breaking <strong>the</strong>se bottlenecks canadvance <strong>the</strong> prospects <strong>of</strong> noninflationary expansion <strong>of</strong> total employment.The o<strong>the</strong>r issues, discussed below, may be resolved differently dependingon which purpose is to be served by a particular training program.(2) The relative responsibilities <strong>of</strong> public agencies and private employersneed to be evaluated. Despite <strong>the</strong> large expansion <strong>of</strong> public manpowertraining, private training activities greatly exceed public. Obviously, <strong>the</strong>incentive for employers to provide training varies, depending on <strong>the</strong> nature<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> skills involved, <strong>the</strong> character <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> industry and <strong>the</strong> characteristics<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> trainees. In many cases, no single employer in an industry may havean economic incentive to train workers many <strong>of</strong> whom will work for hiscompetitors or employers in o<strong>the</strong>r industries. Devising special forms <strong>of</strong>incentive or subsidy which would induce private employers to expand <strong>the</strong>irown training programs is a challenging problem. So far as possible suchincentives should avoid rewarding employers for what <strong>the</strong>y are already doingand what is already advantageous for <strong>the</strong>m to do.(3) Fur<strong>the</strong>r study is needed <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> relative merits—in public training programs—<strong>of</strong>institutional versus on-<strong>the</strong>-job training, and—within institutionaltraining—<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> contribution that can be made by regular educationalinstitutions <strong>of</strong> various types.(4) The relative importance to be given to <strong>the</strong> work and <strong>the</strong> trainingaspects <strong>of</strong> work-training programs needs to be specifically considered.There may be clear public purposes to be served in employing <strong>the</strong> disadvantagedin such programs, particularly in <strong>the</strong> city ghettos, whe<strong>the</strong>r ornot any significant training emerges as a byproduct, and even if <strong>the</strong> jobshave something <strong>of</strong> a "make-work" character. Advocates <strong>of</strong> certain types<strong>of</strong> work-training programs are proposing a system <strong>of</strong> residual public employmentfor persons o<strong>the</strong>rwise unemployable, with training as one ostensiblepurpose. Yet <strong>the</strong> design <strong>of</strong> a program may be such that many <strong>of</strong> thoseinitially enrolled are unlikely ever to be prepared to move on to regularjobs. There may well be a useful role for such programs, but <strong>the</strong> issuesand purposes involved need to be frankly faced.(5) The proliferation <strong>of</strong> Federal, local government, and private trainingprograms—<strong>of</strong>ten designed to serve <strong>the</strong> same or overlapping clienteles—has led to a number <strong>of</strong> problems and some inefficiency and duplication, particularlyat <strong>the</strong> local level. Recent Federal efforts have been devoted toimproving this coordination, and good results are being achieved in a number<strong>of</strong> cities under <strong>the</strong> leadership <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong>'s Committee on Manpower.There are also problems <strong>of</strong> coordinating training activities in local areaswith o<strong>the</strong>r programs designed to serve disadvantaged groups. There haveIII


also been problems, now being resolved, <strong>of</strong> coordinating program planningand management at <strong>the</strong> national level <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Government.(6) New methods need to be developed for finding, reaching, andmotivating more <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> unemployed to undertake training. This requiresanalysis <strong>of</strong> incentives, such as training bonuses, earnings allowances for personsreceiving public assistance, provision <strong>of</strong> day care centers for mo<strong>the</strong>rs <strong>of</strong>dependent children, training allowances for long-term unemployed whohave exhausted <strong>the</strong>ir unemployment insurance benefits, and many o<strong>the</strong>rissues.(7) Most generally, a great deal more study and evaluation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>effectiveness <strong>of</strong> existing training programs is needed. Very little systematicstudy and evaluation has yet been made <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rapidly expandingFederal activity in this field. Most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> programs are still very new.Moreover, since some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m are intended to solve problems <strong>of</strong> specialdifficulty, <strong>the</strong>re is no traditional standard against which to measure effectiveness.It may cost several times as much to prepare an illiterate youthfrom <strong>the</strong> slums for employment as it does to improve <strong>the</strong> skills <strong>of</strong> a literateadult with previous work experience. Yet <strong>the</strong> investments may well beequally rewarding for society. The increase in productivity which canresult is only one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economic benefits, and <strong>the</strong> benefits are not onlyeconomic. Never<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong> objectives and benefits should, as far as possible,be quantified and compared with <strong>the</strong> costs. This is surely importantwhere alternative programs serve essentially <strong>the</strong> same objectives. Substantialresearch is needed on <strong>the</strong> effectiveness <strong>of</strong> different, and particularly<strong>of</strong> new, training techniques.Considerably more knowledge <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> population that can benefit from<strong>the</strong> various kinds <strong>of</strong> training can help in designing more effective programs.The Government plans a large sample survey early in 1968 to collect moredetailed information on <strong>the</strong> nature, extent, causes, and concentration <strong>of</strong> unemploymentand poverty throughout <strong>the</strong> United States. In addition, specialsurveys <strong>of</strong> ghettos and depressed areas in large metropolitan cities areplanned by <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Labor. The information will be extremelyuseful for improving <strong>the</strong> effectiveness <strong>of</strong> existing manpower programs, andfor designing new programs to combat <strong>the</strong> unemployment and poverty thatremain during a period <strong>of</strong> extended prosperity.It is now clear that large sums will be spent for training, over a considerableperiod <strong>of</strong> years. Because <strong>the</strong> objectives are vitally importantand <strong>the</strong>ir attainment costly, every possible effort must be made to increase<strong>the</strong> effectiveness <strong>of</strong> training programs. The Federal Government willundertake this year an intensive general review and assessment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Nation'sneeds for training and retraining, <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> effectiveness <strong>of</strong> variousmethods, <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> organization <strong>of</strong> training efforts, and <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> relative responsibilities<strong>of</strong> Government and industry.Expanded and improved manpower training—both public and private—is an essential requirement for achieving fur<strong>the</strong>r reductions <strong>of</strong> unemployment112


in a context <strong>of</strong> general price stability. Through providing <strong>the</strong> skillsneeded by an economy undergoing rapid technological change, and helpingthose who are presently unemployable or only marginally employable tobecome productive workers, manpower training—along with improved jobplacement and job counselling, and a reduction <strong>of</strong> discrimination—canpermit a more rapid rate <strong>of</strong> economic growth involving progressively fulleruse <strong>of</strong> human resources. It can help <strong>the</strong> Nation avoid <strong>the</strong> painful choicebetween <strong>the</strong> two goals <strong>of</strong> lower unemployment and stable prices. Moreimportantly, it serves larger human purposes.Although precise targets cannot be set for <strong>the</strong> ultimate minimum level<strong>of</strong> unemployment or <strong>the</strong> speed <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> downward movement, it is clearlyunnecessary and undesirable to accept 4-percent unemployment as a permanentobjective <strong>of</strong> U.S. economic policy.IMPROVING THE PERFORMANCE OF PRODUCT MARKETSProgress toward <strong>the</strong> goal <strong>of</strong> fuller utilization <strong>of</strong> resources along with pricestability will require improving <strong>the</strong> performance not only <strong>of</strong> labor marketsbut <strong>of</strong> product markets as well.Active and vigorous competition <strong>of</strong>fers <strong>the</strong> strongest defense against <strong>the</strong>tendency for prices to rise as full utilization <strong>of</strong> resources is approached.When competition is weak, pr<strong>of</strong>it margins in a prosperous economy arelikely to be high. To be sure, high pr<strong>of</strong>it margins, once established, makeno fur<strong>the</strong>r direct contribution to rising prices. But to <strong>the</strong> extent that <strong>the</strong>higher pr<strong>of</strong>it margins <strong>of</strong> a strong economy are initially achieved throughprice increases, <strong>the</strong> price level is directly affected. Moreover, high pr<strong>of</strong>itsunderstandably provide inviting targets for union wage demands. Firmswith strong market power may grant large wage increases, maintaining <strong>the</strong>irpr<strong>of</strong>it margins by raising prices. To minimize such upward ratcheting <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> price structure, it is essential to maintain and streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> forces <strong>of</strong>competition wherever possible.Government action can improve <strong>the</strong> operation <strong>of</strong> product markets ino<strong>the</strong>r ways. Effective regulation can increase efficiency and reduce pricesfor essential utility services. And <strong>the</strong> numerous programs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> FederalGovernment which directly or indirectly affect costs or prices can andshould be administered in a way which attempts to avoid unnecessary orunintended upward pressure on prices, and where possible to alleviate suchpressures.STRENGTHENING COMPETITIONThe virtues and benefits <strong>of</strong> free competition have long been among <strong>the</strong>fundamental premises <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> American system. The dynamic growth andvigor <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> U.S. economy and this country's position <strong>of</strong> industrial leadershipin <strong>the</strong> world have in good part reflected <strong>the</strong> emphasis which publicpolicy has placed on encouraging and streng<strong>the</strong>ning competition.


The promotion <strong>of</strong> competition reflects values o<strong>the</strong>r than purely economicones, and economic values o<strong>the</strong>r than those related strictly to costs andprices. However, one principal reason why competition in product marketsis supported is that it spurs firms to control or reduce costs, and insuresthat <strong>the</strong> benefits <strong>of</strong> cost stability or cost reduction are passed on to consumers.The intensity <strong>of</strong> competition among <strong>the</strong> firms producing a given line <strong>of</strong>products or services varies widely among <strong>the</strong> many sectors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Americaneconomy. In many lines individual firms have virtually no control overprices. Their product prices are set by <strong>the</strong> market in almost <strong>the</strong> same wayas are prices for soybeans or livestock. At <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r extreme <strong>the</strong>re are sectorswhere strong market power makes it possible for firms to establish priceswhich yield good pr<strong>of</strong>its even when capacity utilization is low, and rapidlyexpanding pr<strong>of</strong>its as utilization rates move up. In many o<strong>the</strong>r product lines,producers have some degree <strong>of</strong> market power, <strong>the</strong> effectiveness <strong>of</strong> whichvaries with <strong>the</strong> state <strong>of</strong> capacity utilization.The market power <strong>of</strong> firms is limited not only by <strong>the</strong> competition <strong>of</strong> existingrival producers <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> same product but also—though again in varying degrees—by<strong>the</strong> potential entry <strong>of</strong> new producers (sometimes including <strong>the</strong>industry's own customers) and by competition from producers <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rproducts and services. In today's world <strong>of</strong> rapid technological change, completelynew products or services—<strong>of</strong>ten produced by firms in ano<strong>the</strong>r industry—mayprovide <strong>the</strong> strongest competition for established products (forexample, plastics with metals, automatic washers with laundries, televisionwith movies).The intensity <strong>of</strong> competition has been substantially increased in recentyears by <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> international trade and <strong>the</strong> gradual reduction <strong>of</strong> barriersto such trade. U.S. firms seek markets all over <strong>the</strong> world and foreignfirms are increasingly active in U.S. markets.Actual and potential competition is a powerful force restraining unnecessaryprice increases, promoting product improvement, and inducing firmsto seek efficiency and to find new methods for producing at lower cost.The effectiveness <strong>of</strong> competition is maintained and increased through vigorousenforcement <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> antitrust laws.It is essential to apply <strong>the</strong> law against collusion among competitors to fixprices or to share markets. Antitrust efforts are also designed to combatpractices which streng<strong>the</strong>n market power through reducing <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong>firms in an industry, which erect artificial barriers to <strong>the</strong> entry <strong>of</strong> potentialcompetitors, which delay <strong>the</strong> introduction <strong>of</strong> superior products or cost reducingtechniques, or which serve to blunt <strong>the</strong> effectiveness <strong>of</strong> competitiveprice changes. Such practices raise prices for consumers or reduce <strong>the</strong>quality <strong>of</strong> goods which people can buy.The antitrust statutes assume particular importance in an economy operatingnear <strong>the</strong> limits <strong>of</strong> its capacity. Their vigorous enforcement cancounter a possible inflationary bias in product markets by sustaining andstreng<strong>the</strong>ning competition. Antitrust activities should continue to be fo-114


cused on this main purpose. In particular, effective antitrust cannotprovide for <strong>the</strong> protection <strong>of</strong> individual competitors at <strong>the</strong> expense <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>protection <strong>of</strong> competition.In some areas, unfortunately, <strong>the</strong> thrust <strong>of</strong> protective efforts has beendiverted. For example, during <strong>the</strong> early 1930's many States acted to restrictcompetition in <strong>the</strong> field <strong>of</strong> retail distribution when <strong>the</strong> pervasive economicdistress bankrupted many small firms and threatened countless o<strong>the</strong>rs withfailure. Relief was sought, and frequently obtained, in <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> restrictionson <strong>the</strong> pricing policies <strong>of</strong> larger and more efficient firms—especiallychain stores and mail order houses.RESALE PRICE MAINTENANCEResale price maintenance is such a device, largely born in <strong>the</strong> 1930 J s,which can impair <strong>the</strong> competitive forces <strong>of</strong> free markets. It permits <strong>the</strong>manufacturer <strong>of</strong> a branded product to enter into agreements with one ormore retailers in a State, establishing a minimum resale price for that product.These agreements <strong>the</strong>n become binding on all retailers in that State,regardless <strong>of</strong> whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y have signed <strong>the</strong>m. Today, resale price maintenancelaws are on <strong>the</strong> books <strong>of</strong> 40 States but, as <strong>the</strong> result <strong>of</strong> a series <strong>of</strong>adverse legal decisions, <strong>the</strong> nonsigner clause has been nullified in some States,and <strong>the</strong> laws are now fully effective in less than 20 States. In those States,firms entering into and affected by price maintenance agreements are exemptedfrom <strong>the</strong> Federal antitrust statutes as a result <strong>of</strong> amendments adoptedfor that specific purpose. In recent years, proposals have been made inCongress to amend fur<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> antitrust laws so as to exempt resale pricemaintenance agreements from <strong>the</strong> antitrust laws throughout <strong>the</strong> UnitedStates. The Administration has consistently opposed such legislation.Resale price maintenance permits manufacturers to guarantee attractivemargins to retailers in order to encourage <strong>the</strong>m to promote <strong>the</strong>ir productsra<strong>the</strong>r than those <strong>of</strong> competitors. But by providing a shield from competition,price maintenance agreements <strong>of</strong>ten raise prices to consumers. Moreover,<strong>the</strong>y can induce <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> excess capacity in some branches<strong>of</strong> retailing, as well as blunt price competition in manufacturing industriesdominated by a small number <strong>of</strong> large firms.While resale price maintenance is used for many products, includinghousehold appliances, cosmetics, beverages, and many o<strong>the</strong>r items, it is mostextensively used in <strong>the</strong> sale <strong>of</strong> pharmaceutical supplies and proprietarydrugs. Because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> adoption <strong>of</strong> Medicare and <strong>the</strong> growing public concernwith improvement in health standards, it is particularly important toevaluate <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> resale price maintenance for this group <strong>of</strong> products.A basic purpose <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> antitrust laws is <strong>the</strong> maintenance <strong>of</strong> a market systemin which many firms can operate effectively. But protection <strong>of</strong> inefficientfirms is not a purpose <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> antitrust laws. A small number <strong>of</strong> verylarge firms will not dominate retail markets in a competitive environment.For one thing, entry costs in retailing are typically low, so that any attempt"5


to seize and hold a dominating market share in any major retail marketwould be futile.Whatever <strong>the</strong> case may have been in <strong>the</strong> 1930's for depression-bornmodifications <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> basic competitive philosophy, that case does not applyin today's and tomorrow's expanding economy. In a healthy and viablemarket economy, effective competition will inevitably see some enterprisesfalter and go under. But vigorous new firms will be created, and thosewith effective managements will survive, prosper, and grow. Prices in marketsprotected from competition will be higher on <strong>the</strong> average and lessresponsive to changes in economic conditions and consumer demands.RESTRICTIONS ON INTERNATIONAL TRADEForeign competition can be as effective as domestic competition in forcingproducers to hold down costs and prices. This is one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> reasons why,for many years, U.S. policy has been directed toward a free and open worldtrading system with a minimum <strong>of</strong> restrictions on <strong>the</strong> flow <strong>of</strong> goods andservices across national boundaries. In such a system, <strong>the</strong> spur to specializationand productivity which is provided by international competition servesnot only U.S. commercial interests but those <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> U.S. consumer as well.While <strong>the</strong> reduction <strong>of</strong> trade barriers will, in time, benefit all, it can raisetemporary problems for both industry and labor. These problems areobviously considerably less serious during periods <strong>of</strong> full employment.Never<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong>y exist even <strong>the</strong>n. The burden <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se problems can bereduced in several ways. First, barriers to trade can be relaxed gradually.The tariff cuts expected under <strong>the</strong> Kennedy Round will be made over a5-year period. Second, where an industry or its workers or both are seriouslyinjured through a reduction <strong>of</strong> protection, <strong>the</strong>y can ei<strong>the</strong>r receive renewedprotection from import competition through an "escape clause" action, or<strong>the</strong>y can qualify for "adjustment assistance"—temporary financial and o<strong>the</strong>rassistance to help <strong>the</strong>m adjust to <strong>the</strong> new situation. The latter approach isto be preferred, since <strong>the</strong> costs to <strong>the</strong> economy <strong>of</strong> such support are generallyconsiderably lower than those <strong>of</strong> trade restrictions, and <strong>the</strong> assistance dealswith <strong>the</strong> underlying problem ra<strong>the</strong>r than with its symptoms. The <strong>President</strong>recently lifted escape clause protection on watches, which had been in effectsince 1954, and reduced it for glass.REGULATORY POLICIESSome major sectors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy are subject to extensive Governmentregulation. In <strong>the</strong>se sectors where competition is not considered feasiblebecause <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> wastes <strong>of</strong> duplicative service, regulation substitutes for competitionin keeping prices reasonable and service adequate. These regulatedindustries are vitally important; <strong>the</strong>y not only originate about one-fifth <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> national income, but <strong>the</strong>y include <strong>the</strong> very sinews <strong>of</strong> a modern economy—electric power, communications, and transportation. The markets and116


technologies <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se industries are subject to <strong>the</strong> forces <strong>of</strong> persistent change,which requires that existing policies be continually reexamined.The broad issues are <strong>of</strong>ten <strong>the</strong> same as for <strong>the</strong> nonregulated sectors. Regulation,like o<strong>the</strong>r Government policies, must not be diverted to protecting<strong>the</strong> established positions <strong>of</strong> particular firms or industries at <strong>the</strong> expense <strong>of</strong>economic efficiency. Nor must excessive reliance on uniform prices preclude<strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> price differences to achieve <strong>the</strong> best use <strong>of</strong> capital intensive technologies.Finally, regulatory policy must not forego <strong>the</strong> possibilities <strong>of</strong>introducing competition when technological change makes this economicallydesirable.A vigilant program <strong>of</strong> regulation makes a special contribution to pricestability by holding <strong>the</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> essential utility services at <strong>the</strong> lowest levelsconsistent with <strong>the</strong>ir costs (including necessary pr<strong>of</strong>its), <strong>the</strong>reby helpingdirectly to stabilize or reduce <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> living and <strong>the</strong> costs <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r businesses.The opportunities for price reduction are particularly promising because<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> special economic characteristics <strong>of</strong> at least some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> regulatedindustries. In several <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m, a high elasticity <strong>of</strong> demand (price reductionsincrease volume greatly) coexists with large economies <strong>of</strong> scale (increasedvolumes lower unit costs). As a result, significant price reductions maysometimes be achieved with little adverse effect on pr<strong>of</strong>its and in some caseswith a favorable effect.Fur<strong>the</strong>r, public utilities, communications, and some sectors <strong>of</strong> transportationhave experienced particularly rapid productivity gains. In somecases, wage increases have exceeded those elsewhere in <strong>the</strong> economy, andmay well have been inconsistent with <strong>the</strong> standards for wage-price behaviordiscussed in <strong>the</strong> next section.In <strong>the</strong>se circumstances, regulation is not adequate if it merely protectsconsumers against excessive price increases. It must be alert to make certainthat <strong>the</strong> economy realizes <strong>the</strong> opportunities for lower prices and improvedservice. In so doing, <strong>of</strong> course, regulation must vigilantly preserve <strong>the</strong>strength <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> regulated industries and <strong>the</strong>ir highly skilled labor force.Low prices at <strong>the</strong> expense <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its insufficient to attract <strong>the</strong> necessarycapital, or wages inadequate to attract <strong>the</strong> necessary labor, in <strong>the</strong> long runbenefit no one. Regulation must be flexible to take prompt advantage <strong>of</strong>changing technology such as new sources <strong>of</strong> power, new channels <strong>of</strong> communication,new modes <strong>of</strong> transportation, and new ways <strong>of</strong> using old modes.At times, such innovations will permit <strong>the</strong> scope <strong>of</strong> Government regulationto shrink in favor <strong>of</strong> greater emphasis on competition.Well conceived regulatory activities can contribute to <strong>the</strong> goal <strong>of</strong> maintainingreasonable price stability in a high level economy moving steadilytoward fuller use <strong>of</strong> its human resources.DIRECT GOVERNMENT ACTIONS AFFECTING SUPPLYThe rapid expansion <strong>of</strong> demand during <strong>the</strong> last half <strong>of</strong> 1965 and <strong>the</strong>first part <strong>of</strong> 1966 resulted in numerous bottlenecks which impeded <strong>the</strong>117


smooth flow <strong>of</strong> production. In some cases, <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> raw materials—especially minerals—could not keep pace with <strong>the</strong> needs <strong>of</strong> industry. Ino<strong>the</strong>rs, an essential piece <strong>of</strong> equipment could not be delivered promptly. Instill o<strong>the</strong>rs, transportation facilities were overloaded. All <strong>the</strong>se impedimentsnaturally aggravated pressure on <strong>the</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> scarce material orcomponent, or <strong>the</strong> finished product, or both.Many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se problems could only be alleviated by <strong>the</strong> passage <strong>of</strong> time,and some still persist. In a considerable number <strong>of</strong> instances, however,Government could and did find ways <strong>of</strong> assisting.Scarcities <strong>of</strong> mineral raw materials were especially prevalent as requirementsfor military hardware and capital equipment <strong>of</strong> all kinds rose sharply.Increases in domestic production <strong>of</strong> minerals take considerable time, andfor many <strong>the</strong> United States is dependent in whole or substantial part onimports. Fortunately, <strong>the</strong>re were substantial supplies <strong>of</strong> such metals ascopper, aluminum, tungsten, vanadium, and columbium in <strong>the</strong> strategicstockpile. As a result <strong>of</strong> changing military technology, <strong>the</strong> necessary securityobjectives for some stockpile commodities could be and had been reduced.Disposal <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> indicated surpluses was phased and accelerated so as to augment<strong>the</strong> supplies <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se critically short materials. Therebymany interruptions <strong>of</strong> production were avoided.Ano<strong>the</strong>r area which received increasing attention during 1966 was that<strong>of</strong> Government procurement. Intensive efforts were made to phase procurementand adjust specifications for both military and civilian purchasesso as to minimize <strong>the</strong> impact on productive facilities and product markets.Arrangements were worked out to this end for <strong>the</strong> closest possible cooperationand consultation between <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Defense and <strong>the</strong> Departments<strong>of</strong> Commerce and Agriculture.The Government also sought to smooth out irregularities in <strong>the</strong> supply<strong>of</strong> farm products by appropriate sales <strong>of</strong> farm commodities from governmentstocks, through judicious programing <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> timing <strong>of</strong> P.L. 480 exports,and through <strong>the</strong> adjustment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> timing <strong>of</strong> purchases by Governmentagencies. In response to increased export demands and in order to rebuilddepleted stocks, <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture adjusted productionprograms to elicit increased production <strong>of</strong> wheat, feed grain, and soybeansduring 1967.As specific problems developed, o<strong>the</strong>r possible forms <strong>of</strong> Government actionwere explored and taken. Thus, <strong>the</strong> Business and Defense Services Administration<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce was able to expedite delivery<strong>of</strong> critical items <strong>of</strong> equipment on a number <strong>of</strong> occasions. The ForestService <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture took steps to increase <strong>the</strong> cutting<strong>of</strong> timber in <strong>the</strong> Northwest. The Interstate Commerce Commission, workingwith <strong>the</strong> railroads, alleviated freight-car shortages by speeding up <strong>the</strong>turnaround <strong>of</strong> cars at ports and o<strong>the</strong>r delivery points and by pressing for amore appropriate distribution <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> cars available.n8


It is likely that 1967 will bring more problems <strong>of</strong> this kind, though <strong>the</strong>ywill not recur in exactly <strong>the</strong> same form. However, <strong>the</strong> experience <strong>of</strong> 1966demonstrates that Government can make a significant contribution tosmoothing <strong>the</strong> flow <strong>of</strong> production and <strong>the</strong>reby lessening pressures on prices.WAGE-PRICE POLICIESVigorous competition is essential to price stability in a high employmenteconomy. But competitive forces do not and cannot operate with equalstrength in every sector <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy. In industries where <strong>the</strong> number<strong>of</strong> competitors is limited, business firms have a substantial measure <strong>of</strong>discretion in setting prices. In many sectors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> labor market, unionsand managements toge<strong>the</strong>r have a substantial measure <strong>of</strong> discretion insetting wages. The responsible exercise <strong>of</strong> discretionary power over wagesand prices can help to maintain general price stability. Its irresponsibleuse can make full employment and price stability incompatible.When demand outruns <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> productive resources, prices andwages will rise even in <strong>the</strong> most highly competitive markets. (Indeed, <strong>the</strong>ymay rise faster and far<strong>the</strong>r than where large firms and long-term labor contractsgive some degree <strong>of</strong> stability.) That kind <strong>of</strong> "demand-pull" inflationcan be held in check by fiscal and monetary policies which keep demand inline with productive capabilities. If labor markets are efficient, control <strong>of</strong>demand-pull inflation will not require restraints on demand that wouldlead to a high unemployment rate.But businesses and unions can push prices up even when resources are notfully utilized. That kind <strong>of</strong> "cost-push" inflation, too, can be controlled bylowering demand, but only at <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> an unacceptable degree <strong>of</strong> economicslack. Frequent recessions, chronically high unemployment, idlecapacity, and a low rate <strong>of</strong> investment may purchase price stability—but<strong>the</strong> cost is too high.The problem <strong>of</strong> cost-push inflation has been a matter <strong>of</strong> concern inthis country and abroad ever since <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> World War II. Shortly after<strong>the</strong> war, when many governments, including our own, declared <strong>the</strong>ir determinationto maintain high employment, many economists predicted that<strong>the</strong> irresponsible exercise <strong>of</strong> market power in an era <strong>of</strong> high employmentwould lead to progressively faster rates <strong>of</strong> inflation.These fears were exaggerated. But cost-push inflation has been aproblem in many countries. A number <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m have adopted formal"incomes policies" as a means <strong>of</strong> limiting inflation. In <strong>the</strong> United States,efforts to influence <strong>the</strong> general level <strong>of</strong> prices through a national wage-pricepolicy have emerged gradually during <strong>the</strong> period since World War II.These efforts have relied on education, persuasion, and voluntary coopera-


tion. For example, <strong>the</strong> 1957 <strong>Economic</strong> <strong>Report</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> (pp. 2-3)included <strong>the</strong> following paragraphs:A fur<strong>the</strong>r responsibility <strong>of</strong> leaders <strong>of</strong> management and labor in a freeeconomy derives from <strong>the</strong> fact that concentrations <strong>of</strong> power place in <strong>the</strong>irhands <strong>the</strong> ability to take actions that, through <strong>the</strong> sensitive network <strong>of</strong> oureconomic system, significantly affect <strong>the</strong> Nation as a whole.Specifically, business and labor leadership have <strong>the</strong> responsibility to reachagreements on wages and o<strong>the</strong>r labor benefits that are fair to <strong>the</strong> rest <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> community as well as to those persons immediately involved. Negotiatedwage increases and benefits should be consistent with productivity prospectsand with <strong>the</strong> maintenance <strong>of</strong> a stable dollar. And businesses must recognize<strong>the</strong> broad public interest in <strong>the</strong> prices set on <strong>the</strong>ir products and services.In <strong>the</strong> introduction to his 1958 <strong>Economic</strong> <strong>Report</strong> (p. v), <strong>President</strong>Eisenhower wrote:Business managements must recognize that price increases that areunwarranted by costs, or that attempt to recapture investment outlays tooquickly, not only lower <strong>the</strong> buying power <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> dollar, but also may beself-defeating by causing a restriction <strong>of</strong> markets, lower output, and anarrowing <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> return on capital investment. The leadership <strong>of</strong> labormust recognize that wage increases that go beyond over-all productivitygains are inconsistent with stable prices, and that <strong>the</strong> resumption <strong>of</strong> economicgrowth can be slowed by wage increases that involve ei<strong>the</strong>r higher prices ora fur<strong>the</strong>r narrowing <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> margin between prices and costs.These injunctions were given more precise content in <strong>the</strong> "Wage-PriceGuideposts" <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1962 <strong>Report</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers.THE COUNCIL'S WAGE-PRICE GUIDEPOSTSThe 1962 <strong>Report</strong> started from <strong>the</strong> premise that <strong>the</strong>re are important segments<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy in which large firms or well-organized groups <strong>of</strong> employeeshave some discretionary ability to affect <strong>the</strong> levels <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir pricesand wages. Such decisions affect <strong>the</strong> public interest. An informed public<strong>the</strong>refore should have standards by which to judge—and, by judging, toinfluence—those decisions. The Council proposed a set <strong>of</strong> standards forthis purpose as a contribution to public discussion.These standards—like those more generally described in <strong>the</strong> statementsquoted above—are based on certain arithmetical relationships among outputper man-hour (productivity), wage rates, and prices. These relationshipsshow that, if wage rates increase in line with output per man-hour,prices can be stable while <strong>the</strong> distribution <strong>of</strong> income between labor ando<strong>the</strong>rs contributing to production remains unchanged.Since this arithmetic is frequently not understood, it will be useful to givean example. If a worker in a particular firm is paid $2 an hour—$80 aweek—and contributes to <strong>the</strong> production <strong>of</strong> 200 units a week, output perman-hour is 5 units (200 units divided by 40 hours) and unit labor cost is$.40 ($80 divided by 200 units). If, for whatever reason, output rises by 3percent, to 206 units a week—with no extra labor time required—outputper man-hour is also up 3 percent, to 5.15 units (206 units divided by 40hours). If <strong>the</strong> wage rate also rises by 3 percent, to $2.06 an hour ($82.40 aweek), unit labor costs will remain at $.40 ($82.40 divided by 206 units). If<strong>the</strong> price <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> product is unchanged, <strong>the</strong> margin between price and unitI2O


labor cost—available to pay for o<strong>the</strong>rs' contributions to production—will be<strong>the</strong> same. But with 3 percent more units sold, <strong>the</strong> total amount availableto pay o<strong>the</strong>rs, including owners, will also rise by 3 percent.If productivity were to advance at <strong>the</strong> same pace in every industry, <strong>the</strong>same result would apply to <strong>the</strong> whole economy. But productivity grows atdifferent rates in different industries. If <strong>the</strong> wage rate in each industryshould rise at <strong>the</strong> same rate as productivity in that industry, <strong>the</strong> prices <strong>of</strong>each industry's products could be stable, and <strong>the</strong> distribution <strong>of</strong> income betweenwages and pr<strong>of</strong>its would be unchanged both within each industry andin <strong>the</strong> entire economy. But some wage rates would rise hardly at all whileo<strong>the</strong>rs would rise rapidly. That result would clearly be unsatisfactory, for,after a time, workers with similar skills in different industries would bereceiving widely different wages.Alternatively, <strong>the</strong> yearly percentage increase in hourly wages and fringebenefits in each industry could be <strong>the</strong> same, equal to <strong>the</strong> average yearly percentagerise in output per man-hour over <strong>the</strong> whole economy. Then <strong>the</strong>average <strong>of</strong> unit labor costs in <strong>the</strong> whole economy would be stable, althoughrising in some industries and declining in o<strong>the</strong>rs. If prices in each industrywere to change correspondingly, rising in some and falling in o<strong>the</strong>rs, <strong>the</strong>y,too, would be stable on <strong>the</strong> average. The sharing <strong>of</strong> gross income betweenlabor and ownership would <strong>the</strong>n be unchanged in each industry, and for<strong>the</strong> economy as a whole. This is <strong>the</strong> arithmetic which underlies <strong>the</strong> Council's1962 guideposts.The advance <strong>of</strong> productivity from year to year is far from uniform, eventhough its general trend is reasonably clear. The 1962 <strong>Report</strong> related <strong>the</strong>guideposts to <strong>the</strong> trend <strong>of</strong> productivity over a period <strong>of</strong> years, ra<strong>the</strong>r thanto year-to-year changes. This meant that <strong>the</strong> rise in average hourly wagesand fringes should be steady and smooth, not erratic. Moreover, <strong>the</strong>problem <strong>of</strong> trying to estimate <strong>the</strong> particular movement <strong>of</strong> average productivityover <strong>the</strong> period to be covered by a given wage agreement was avoided.Consequently, pr<strong>of</strong>its would vary with short-run movements in productivity;and <strong>the</strong> stable distribution <strong>of</strong> income between labor and ownership would<strong>the</strong>n be achieved only on <strong>the</strong> average over a period <strong>of</strong> years.The 1962 Wage GuidepostThe <strong>Report</strong> proposed as a general rule that hourly labor compensationshould advance in accordance with <strong>the</strong> trend increase in productivity in <strong>the</strong>entire economy. No specific estimate was given <strong>of</strong> that trend, althougha summary <strong>of</strong> statistical evidence on <strong>the</strong> long-run growth <strong>of</strong> output perman-hour was provided.The general guidepost rule was subject to various exceptions—some explicitlystated and o<strong>the</strong>rs only suggested. The stated exceptions were <strong>the</strong>se:In <strong>the</strong> interest <strong>of</strong> equity, wages <strong>of</strong> workers who are underpaid because <strong>of</strong>weak bargaining power (or o<strong>the</strong>r reasons) should rise faster than <strong>the</strong>average, while wages <strong>of</strong> workers who are overpaid because <strong>of</strong> exceptionally121


strong bargaining power should rise more slowly than <strong>the</strong> average. In <strong>the</strong>interest <strong>of</strong> efficiency, wages should rise somewhat faster than <strong>the</strong> average inindustries with a rapidly growing employment (in order to aid recruitment),and more slowly in industries with labor surpluses. Moreover, workers whocontributed to an extra rise in <strong>the</strong>ir own productivity—for example, byconsenting to <strong>the</strong> relaxation or removal <strong>of</strong> restraints on <strong>the</strong> freedom <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>iremployers to change work rules or introduce new methods—should beallowed to share in <strong>the</strong> benefits <strong>of</strong> that extra productivity gain.The <strong>Report</strong> suggested, without listing <strong>the</strong>m, that <strong>the</strong>re were o<strong>the</strong>r factorswhich could justify deviations from <strong>the</strong> general rule. One such factormay be <strong>the</strong> recent history <strong>of</strong> wage movements: if wages for one group <strong>of</strong>workers have increased faster than <strong>the</strong> productivity trend in <strong>the</strong> recentpast, <strong>the</strong>y should rise more slowly now, and vice versa. Moreover, <strong>the</strong>remight be occasions for <strong>the</strong> removal <strong>of</strong> glaring inequities between wages indifferent plants, areas, or occupations which—although <strong>the</strong>y created noimmediate labor supply problems—might do so in <strong>the</strong> long run if notcorrected. Presumably this would be accomplished both by slower increasesfor <strong>the</strong> favored groups as well as by faster increases for <strong>the</strong> disadvantaged.No reference was made to any deviation from <strong>the</strong> general rule because<strong>of</strong> a rise in consumer prices—an issue to be discussed below.If <strong>the</strong> wage guidepost were generally observed by organized groups <strong>of</strong>workers with discretion over <strong>the</strong>ir wage rates, and <strong>the</strong>re were no excessdemand in <strong>the</strong> economy, <strong>the</strong> 1962 <strong>Report</strong> assumed that compensation inunorganized sectors would rise at <strong>the</strong> same average rate, equal to <strong>the</strong> gainin over-all productivity. If this were <strong>the</strong> case, <strong>the</strong>n hourly wages plusfringes in all industries would rise by about <strong>the</strong> same percentage, and byabout that same percentage every year. The average <strong>of</strong> unit labor costs in<strong>the</strong> economy Would be unchanged in <strong>the</strong> average year.But unit labor costs would not be unchanged in each industry. In someindustries—in which <strong>the</strong> trend <strong>of</strong> productivity exceeded <strong>the</strong> generalaverage—unit labor costs would show a downward trend. In o<strong>the</strong>rs—where <strong>the</strong> trend <strong>of</strong> productivity was below <strong>the</strong> over-all average—unit laborcosts would show an upward trend.The 1962 Price GuidepostThe general guidepost rule for prices was that—in industries in which <strong>the</strong> trend <strong>of</strong> productivity about equaled <strong>the</strong>average for <strong>the</strong> economy, prices should be stable;—in industries in which <strong>the</strong> trend <strong>of</strong> productivity was steeper than <strong>the</strong>average, prices should fall; and—in industries in which <strong>the</strong> trend <strong>of</strong> productivity was below <strong>the</strong>average, prices could appropriately rise.It has been noted, however, that <strong>the</strong> over-all productivity gain <strong>of</strong> anygiven year will diverge from <strong>the</strong> trend. Such divergences from trend arceven more pronounced in individual industries. Thus in particular years,122


unit labor costs might rise or fall for a particular industry without affecting<strong>the</strong> recommended trend <strong>of</strong> prices for that industry. This would result inyear-to-year changes in <strong>the</strong> sharing <strong>of</strong> gross business income between laborand ownership—both in individual industries and in <strong>the</strong> whole economy.Corresponding to <strong>the</strong> exceptions to <strong>the</strong> general wage guidepost, <strong>the</strong>rewere exceptions to <strong>the</strong> general rule for prices. Prices could rise more than<strong>the</strong> general rule would indicate in an industry in which pr<strong>of</strong>its were inadequateto attract <strong>the</strong> capital to finance a needed expansion in capacity,or costs o<strong>the</strong>r than labor costs had risen. Prices should fall, in comparisonwith <strong>the</strong> general guidepost rule, in industries where productive capacity wasexcessive or where costs o<strong>the</strong>r than labor costs had fallen. Prices shouldalso fall, in comparison with <strong>the</strong> general rule, where "excessive marketpower had resulted in rates <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it substantially higher than those earnedelsewhere on investments <strong>of</strong> comparable risk."Although <strong>the</strong> price guidepost was directed only at industries in whichfirms possessed some pricing discretion, <strong>the</strong> 1962 <strong>Report</strong> assumed that ifprices in <strong>the</strong>se industries conformed to <strong>the</strong> guideposts, <strong>the</strong> average <strong>of</strong> priceswould also be stable in <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, highly competitive industries (includingagriculture and most services) where firms had no discretion. If this weretrue, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> average <strong>of</strong> all prices would be stable. And since moneywages would have advanced by <strong>the</strong> same percentage as productivity, <strong>the</strong>advance <strong>of</strong> real wages would equal <strong>the</strong> advance in productivity.The Guideposts in Subsequent Council <strong>Report</strong>s<strong>Report</strong>s <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Council since 1962 have preserved <strong>the</strong> general concepts<strong>of</strong> wage and price guideposts presented in <strong>the</strong> 1962 <strong>Report</strong>. However, <strong>the</strong>Council has given increasingly clear indications <strong>of</strong> what it regarded as <strong>the</strong>trend <strong>of</strong> productivity which should govern wage movements. In <strong>the</strong> 1966<strong>Report</strong> <strong>the</strong> Council specifically recommended that <strong>the</strong> general wageguidepost be 3.2 percent a year.Most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> exceptions to <strong>the</strong> general guideposts, both for wages andfor prices, that were explicitly stated in <strong>the</strong> 1962 <strong>Report</strong> have continued toappear in subsequent <strong>Report</strong>s. However, <strong>the</strong> possible applicability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>seexceptions has been less emphasized. And <strong>the</strong> possibility <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, unspecifiedexceptions has not been mentioned. Moreover, whereas <strong>the</strong> 1962 <strong>Report</strong> hademphasized that <strong>the</strong> guideposts were "guides" not "rules," and werepresented as a "basis for discussion," subsequent statements by <strong>the</strong> Counciland o<strong>the</strong>rs in <strong>the</strong> Administration have been interpreted as treating <strong>the</strong>guideposts as firm, though voluntary, rules, and those who fail to adhereto <strong>the</strong>m as "violators."How <strong>the</strong> Guidepost Policy Has WorkedIn <strong>the</strong> areas in which <strong>the</strong> guideposts were expected to apply—amongstrongly organized groups <strong>of</strong> workers and in firms which have appreciable123


discretion with regard to <strong>the</strong>ir prices—<strong>the</strong> guideposts were reasonably wellobserved, at least until mid-1966.Strong labor unions are concentrated in manufacturing, mining, construction,and transportation. Data on <strong>the</strong> average change in hourly earningsor in total compensation for <strong>the</strong> total private economy are <strong>the</strong>refore notparticularly helpful in appraising adherence to <strong>the</strong> wage guidepost.The most relevant figures are <strong>the</strong> fragmentary data on important newcollective bargaining settlements referred to in Chapter 2. These indicatethat until <strong>the</strong> second half <strong>of</strong> 1966 <strong>the</strong> median <strong>of</strong> such settlements (excludingconstruction) was only modestly in excess <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> general wage guidepost.(However, since many were below <strong>the</strong> median, <strong>the</strong>re were also some appreciablyabove.) Construction settlements, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, consistentlyand significantly exceeded <strong>the</strong> general guidepost. Especially in 1966, transportationsettlements (for example, airlines and New York subways) werefar above <strong>the</strong> guidepost. Within manufacturing, automobile wages advancedat a rate much above <strong>the</strong> guidepost, and recent settlements in <strong>the</strong>electrical equipment manufacturing and telephone industries also wereabout 1 /2 percentage points in excess.Never<strong>the</strong>less, a number <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> most significant union settlements—including<strong>the</strong> key steel bargain <strong>of</strong> 1965—were at or close to <strong>the</strong> generalguidepost.It is difficult to generalize about <strong>the</strong> extent to which <strong>the</strong> price decisions<strong>of</strong> firms with price discretion have adhered to <strong>the</strong> guidepost. It is clear thatsome significant price reductions which <strong>the</strong> guidepost would have suggestedhave not occurred. Automobile prices are doubtless such a case. Steelprices have edged up only moderately, on <strong>the</strong> average, but it is possible that<strong>the</strong> guidepost would have permitted some slight increase. The pricing <strong>of</strong>aluminum—particularly <strong>of</strong> fabricated aluminum products—could surelynot have been consistent with <strong>the</strong> general guidepost. Producers <strong>of</strong> steel andaluminum have argued, however, that <strong>the</strong>ir relatively low pr<strong>of</strong>it positionscalled for some price increase in order to retain or attract needed capital.O<strong>the</strong>r important price increases about which guidepost questions might beraised include those for newsprint, gasoline, alloy and specialty steels, somechemicals, and agricultural machinery.For cotton textiles, a sharp decline in <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> raw cotton would havesuggested price reductions; but it can be argued that no individual producerin this highly competitive industry has significant discretion about hisprices, and that what happened was a purely supply-demand response. Thisargument will be tested by what happens to cotton textile prices in <strong>the</strong>months ahead. Prices <strong>of</strong> machine tools and <strong>of</strong> many o<strong>the</strong>r types <strong>of</strong> industrialequipment have undoubtedly risen substantially faster than costs. However,in view <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> excess demand for this category <strong>of</strong> goods, it seems clearthat producers have practiced restraint, and that—in a purely competitivemarket—prices would have risen faster and far<strong>the</strong>r.124


In <strong>the</strong> minerals industries, increases in sulphur and <strong>the</strong> small increase incopper (until January 1967) again are cases in which price restraint hasclearly held prices below levels which would clear <strong>the</strong> market, even thougha pure guidepost policy might not have implied any price increase. Moreover,in <strong>the</strong>se cases, <strong>the</strong> possible need for higher prices to encourage <strong>the</strong> useand development <strong>of</strong> marginal resources complicates any judgment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>public interest in <strong>the</strong>se prices.In general terms, <strong>the</strong> greatest failure <strong>of</strong> observance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> price guidepostlies in <strong>the</strong> failure to reduce prices on a considerable number <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> productlines <strong>of</strong> a large number <strong>of</strong> industries. As Chapter 3 has indicated, a number<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> price increases that have occurred in manufacturing and miningindustries undoubtedly had some justification in higher costs. But <strong>of</strong>fsettingprice decreases have been far too few.GOVERNMENT ACTIVITIES TO PROMOTE GUIDEPOST ADHERENCEThe 1962 <strong>Report</strong> proposed <strong>the</strong> guideposts as a standard for <strong>the</strong> publicto use in judging <strong>the</strong> extent to which private price and wage decisions wereconsistent with <strong>the</strong> public interest in a noninflationary economy. However,<strong>the</strong> message was directed not merely to <strong>the</strong> public but also to labor and tobusiness. The guideposts were designed to define more precisely to laborand business <strong>the</strong> Government's view as to what <strong>the</strong> public interest required<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m. And it was obviously important that labor and business—as wellas <strong>the</strong> public—should understand why observance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se standards wasin <strong>the</strong> public interest, and why it was also in <strong>the</strong> long-run interest <strong>of</strong> bothlabor and business.Clearly, it was not enough merely to publish <strong>the</strong>se standards and assumethat <strong>the</strong> job was done. The public does not have <strong>the</strong> information that wouldpermit it to apply <strong>the</strong> guidepost standards to particular cases <strong>of</strong> wage or pricemovements. Some reporting is necessary to help <strong>the</strong> public make intelligentjudgments <strong>of</strong> labor and business behavior. Likewise, so far as businessand labor are concerned, <strong>the</strong> educational process is not achieved by asingle annual statement.Thus, it is clear that <strong>the</strong> Government must take an active and continuinginterest in interpreting and explaining <strong>the</strong> guideposts to both labor and industryon <strong>the</strong> one hand, and to <strong>the</strong> general public on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r. Indeed,<strong>the</strong>re may even be some conflict between <strong>the</strong> objective <strong>of</strong> effectively persuadinglabor and industry to accept voluntarily <strong>the</strong> disciplines implied by <strong>the</strong>guideposts, and that <strong>of</strong> informing <strong>the</strong> public so that it can focus its judgments,favorable or unfavorable, concerning particular wage settlementsor price changes. The Administration has been gradually feeling its waytoward a proper definition <strong>of</strong> Government's role in <strong>the</strong> process <strong>of</strong> informationand persuasion. Undoubtedly some mistakes have been made. Butsome real progress has been achieved.Three major types <strong>of</strong> activities have been undertaken. First, <strong>the</strong> members<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers, various Cabinet and sub-Cabinet240-782 O—67- 125


<strong>of</strong>ficials, and <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> himself have made numerous addresses about <strong>the</strong>guideposts to business and labor groups and to <strong>the</strong> general public. As mightbe expected, <strong>the</strong> Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers has taken a leading part inthis activity, with literally dozens <strong>of</strong> speeches, articles for <strong>the</strong> popular press,and radio and television appearances. Many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se have received substantialcoverage in both <strong>the</strong> general press and in <strong>the</strong> specialized press <strong>of</strong> anumber <strong>of</strong> industries.The second type <strong>of</strong> activity has been an increasing number <strong>of</strong> privatecommunications and meetings between Government <strong>of</strong>ficials and leaders<strong>of</strong> business and labor designed to underscore <strong>the</strong> public interest factor inwage and price decisions and to solicit <strong>the</strong> cooperation <strong>of</strong> union and corporateleadership in specific situations. With labor organizations, most <strong>of</strong> thisactivity has been carried on by <strong>the</strong> Secretary <strong>of</strong> Labor and his associates.With industry, <strong>the</strong> Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers, <strong>the</strong> Secretaries <strong>of</strong> Commerce,Treasury, Agriculture, Interior, Defense, and o<strong>the</strong>rs have participated.However, since <strong>the</strong> largest number <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se contacts has been madeby <strong>the</strong> Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers, it seems appropriate that <strong>the</strong> Councilshould provide a report on <strong>the</strong>se activities.In <strong>the</strong> past year, <strong>the</strong> Council became involved in regard to perhaps 50product lines for which price increases were ei<strong>the</strong>r imminent or had beenannounced by one or more firms. In <strong>the</strong> typical case, <strong>the</strong> Council learnedin one way or ano<strong>the</strong>r <strong>of</strong> a price increase that was contemplated or thathad been announced by one or more producers. In some instances, companiescontemplating price changes <strong>the</strong>mselves brought <strong>the</strong> subject to <strong>the</strong>Council's attention. Where <strong>the</strong> Council learned <strong>of</strong> an important actual orimpending price increase, its procedure was to send letters-or telegrams toall principal producers <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> product. In urgent cases, telephone callssubstituted for letters or telegrams. If some firms had already announcedprice increases, <strong>the</strong>y were asked to reconsider. Those who had not so announcedwere asked to avoid <strong>the</strong>m if possible. In all cases, an invitationwas extended to meet with <strong>the</strong> Council to discuss <strong>the</strong> matter.In <strong>the</strong> private discussions which <strong>of</strong>ten followed <strong>the</strong>se communications,<strong>the</strong> companies explained <strong>the</strong> reasons why a price increase was consideredappropriate, and <strong>the</strong> Government representatives presented any informationavailable to <strong>the</strong>m which appeared relevant to <strong>the</strong> price decision.The Council recognizes in <strong>the</strong>se meetings that it ordinarily does not have<strong>the</strong> detailed information which would permit a clear judgment as to <strong>the</strong>appropriateness <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> proposed price change on ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> basis <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>guidepost standards or o<strong>the</strong>r relevant considerations. But it explains <strong>the</strong>public interest in price stability, and <strong>the</strong> company is urged to take thisinterest fully into account in making its decision. These meetings areordinarily not reported publicly, unless revealed by <strong>the</strong> company involved.In a few <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> cases that arose in 1966, in which <strong>the</strong> price problems <strong>of</strong>an industry appeared to be ra<strong>the</strong>r general, a number <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> leading producerswere invited to meet with Government representatives to discuss <strong>the</strong> price126


situations in <strong>the</strong>ir industries. Some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se meetings were publiclyreported.The outcome <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se activities cannot be fully known. In a number <strong>of</strong>cases, it is clear that price increases which were announced or contemplatedhave been rescinded, reduced in amount or coverage, or delayed. Somecompanies have indicated that <strong>the</strong>ir subsequent price decisions were affectedeven where <strong>the</strong>ir decision in <strong>the</strong> immediate case was not changed.The response on <strong>the</strong> part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> businesses involved has been extremelyencouraging. Only in rare cases has <strong>the</strong> Council been told that it had noright to question private decisions. Almost invariably <strong>the</strong> companiesinvolved have recognized a larger public interest in <strong>the</strong>ir pricing decisionsand have made a sincere effort to take that interest into account. Somelarge companies agreed to give <strong>the</strong> Council advance notice <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir intentionto change prices.This activity will be continued by <strong>the</strong> Council. It helps to make clear<strong>the</strong> rationale <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> guideposts to business managements in situations where<strong>the</strong>ir interpretation may be unclear. And it provides <strong>the</strong> Council a betterunderstanding <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> problems faced by responsible business leaders.As a third type <strong>of</strong> activity, <strong>the</strong> Council has, on occasion, issued formalstatements to <strong>the</strong> public commenting on particular wage or price decisions.In <strong>the</strong> past year, <strong>the</strong>se included statements on wage increases for employees<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> New York Transit Authority, <strong>the</strong> five airlines involved in <strong>the</strong> July-August strike, and <strong>the</strong> American Airlines case. It issued public statementson price increases for steel (on several occasions), aluminum, copper, andmolybdenum. It responded informally to press questions in o<strong>the</strong>r cases.BASIC PROBLEMS FOR WAGE-PRICE POLICY IN 1967Two important developments have created <strong>the</strong> major problems for wagepricepolicy today. The first is that consumer prices have risen by 3.3percent in <strong>the</strong> past 12 months, which makes organized workers—evenin unions which were previously disposed to cooperate with <strong>the</strong> Government'spolicy—unwilling to contemplate settlements at or close to <strong>the</strong>guideposts. And it gives unions which were never disposed to cooperatean additional reason for not doing so. The second development is thatcorporate pr<strong>of</strong>its have increased considerably more than aggregate laborincome, especially when measured from <strong>the</strong> slack years <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> late 1950'sor <strong>the</strong> recession year <strong>of</strong> 1961. This provides a second reason for labor'sresistance to <strong>the</strong> guidepost.There can be no question that some part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rise in consumer pricesis due to past failure to observe <strong>the</strong> guideposts, both by organized laborand by business. And some part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> faster rise <strong>of</strong> corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its hasbeen due to.<strong>the</strong> failure <strong>of</strong> some businesses to make <strong>the</strong>ir price decisionsconform to <strong>the</strong> guidepost principles (particularly by not reducing someprices when costs fell).127


But it is clear from Chapter 2 that <strong>the</strong> primary source <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rise in consumerprices lies in areas to which <strong>the</strong> guideposts have no applicability: infarm products, where prices have risen considerably, despite rapid productivitygains; and in services, where wages and pr<strong>of</strong>essional incomes <strong>of</strong> unorganizedworkers have also risen rapidly.So far as <strong>the</strong> rise in corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its is concerned, much <strong>of</strong> it would haveoccurred had <strong>the</strong> guideposts been precisely followed. As noted above,<strong>the</strong> year-to-year advance <strong>of</strong> productivity frequently diverges from <strong>the</strong> longtermtrend during years <strong>of</strong> rapid expansion, and did from 1962 at leastthrough 1965. Moreover, greater sales volume and higher operating ratesmeant lower unit capital costs, thus adding to pr<strong>of</strong>its. Consequently, evenif guidepost principles on wages and prices had been literally observed,pr<strong>of</strong>it margins during such a period would have increased sharply, andaggregate pr<strong>of</strong>its even more so. Likewise, <strong>the</strong> leveling <strong>of</strong>f <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its in1966—when productivity gains slowed down—is consistent with <strong>the</strong> guidepostexpectation.Never<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong> rise in consumer prices and <strong>the</strong> increasing share <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>itsuntil <strong>the</strong> first quarter <strong>of</strong> 1966 are facts that cannot be disputed nor explainedout <strong>of</strong> existence. And <strong>the</strong>y cannot fail to influence <strong>the</strong> behavior <strong>of</strong> wagesin 1967. Through <strong>the</strong> effect <strong>of</strong> wages on costs, <strong>the</strong>y will also influence prices.A WAGE-PRICE POLICY FOR 1967The main issues for wage-price policy in 1967 are <strong>the</strong>se:(a) Should <strong>the</strong> guidepost for wages be adjusted to recognize in someway <strong>the</strong> recent increase in living costs?(b) Should fur<strong>the</strong>r recognition be given to special factors—o<strong>the</strong>rthan those previously recognized—which appropriately justify exceptionsto <strong>the</strong> general guidepost principles?(c) To what extent should pr<strong>of</strong>it margins absorb cost increases?Recognition <strong>of</strong> Higher Living CostsThe Council recognizes that <strong>the</strong> recent rise in living costs makes it unlikelythat most collective bargaining settlements in 1967 will fully conformto <strong>the</strong> trend increase <strong>of</strong> productivity. But it sees no useful purpose to beserved by suggesting some higher standard for wage increases, even on atemporary basis.The only valid and noninflationary standard for wage advances is" <strong>the</strong> productivityprinciple. If price stability is eventually to be restored and maintainedin a high-employment U.S. economy, wage settlements must onceagain conform to that standard.While it can be expected that many wage settlements in 1967 will exceed<strong>the</strong> trend increase <strong>of</strong> productivity, it is obvious that if, on <strong>the</strong> average, <strong>the</strong>yshould exceed it by <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> recent increase in living costs, pricestability could never be restored. If <strong>the</strong> average wage increase in 1967were to include a full allowance for productivity plus an additional margin128


to "compensate" for past increases in living costs, unit labor costs would riseat a rate which would require living costs to continue <strong>the</strong>ir rapid rise.In this connection, it must be recognized that some part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> advance<strong>of</strong> consumer prices represents a transfer <strong>of</strong> income to public uses. MostState and local governments are compelled repeatedly to raise indirect taxrates to finance <strong>the</strong> expansion <strong>of</strong> essential services. These indirect taxesenter into prices, accounting for 0.2 percentage point <strong>of</strong> rise in <strong>the</strong> consumerprice index in 1966. And in 1967, <strong>the</strong>re will be no <strong>of</strong>fset to <strong>the</strong> rise in <strong>the</strong>seindirect taxes (as in 1965 and 1966) from reduced Federal excises. If everygroup attempted to <strong>of</strong>fset <strong>the</strong> burden <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se higher indirect taxes by a compensatingrise in money incomes, no transfer <strong>of</strong> real resources to publicpurposes could be achieved.It is not expected that market forces in 1967 will again require that averagewages in <strong>the</strong> largely unorganized sectors—agriculture, trade, and services—should rise faster than in <strong>the</strong> organized segments—manufacturing, mining,construction, and transportation—in order to promote an efficient allocationand use <strong>of</strong> labor. But <strong>the</strong> higher minimum wage effective in 1967 willhave its principal impact on wages in <strong>the</strong> unorganized sectors, and in <strong>the</strong>largely unorganized low-wage segments <strong>of</strong> manufacturing. Thus <strong>the</strong>re willbe some continued pressure on costs and prices originating in wage increasesoutside <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> organized sectors.In 1967, <strong>the</strong> national interest continues to require restraint in wagesettlements; indeed, it is more essential than ever that restraint be practicedin order to turn <strong>the</strong> trend <strong>of</strong> prices back toward stability. If restraintcannot mean an average wage advance only equal to <strong>the</strong> rise in productivity,it surely must mean wage advances which are substantially less than <strong>the</strong>productivity trend plus <strong>the</strong> recent rise in consumer prices.Although <strong>the</strong> Council recognizes that some allowance will frequently bemade for higher living costs in 1967 settlements, it continues to believethat arrangements which automatically tie wage rates to changes in consumerprice indexes will contribute to inflation. One union may be able toprotect its members in this way against any deterioration in its real wage orany real impact from increased indirect taxes. But it does so only by imposingmore <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> burden on o<strong>the</strong>rs. And if all unions—and o<strong>the</strong>r groups insociety—were to succeed in tying compensation to consumer prices, <strong>the</strong>arrangement would become a vast engine <strong>of</strong> inflation, which, once it beganto roll, would continue to gain speed.Guidepost ExceptionsThe most frequent criticism <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> present wage guidepost—after <strong>the</strong>criticism that it fails to allow for <strong>the</strong> rise in consumer prices—is that it failsto provide sufficient exceptions for <strong>the</strong> many special and individual circumstances<strong>of</strong> which account must be taken in wage negotiations. This criticismrequires consideration.129


A guidepost exception has always been made for low wages. In a yearin which <strong>the</strong> minimum wage will advance 11 percent, from $1.25 to $1.40an hour, with an inevitable impact on wages previously near <strong>the</strong> newminimum, this exception is obviously significant. The fact, however, thatfew strong unions exist among low-wage workers gives <strong>the</strong> exception onlylimited relevance for collective bargaining.It surely does not justify large wage increases for high-wage unions.Indeed, <strong>the</strong> productivity arithmetic suggests that, if an exception for lowwageworkers is to be meaningful in permitting low-wage workers to receiveincreases in real wages, high-wage workers who have pr<strong>of</strong>ited in <strong>the</strong>past from exceptionally strong bargaining power must respect <strong>the</strong> counterpartexception that <strong>the</strong>ir wage increases should be less than <strong>the</strong> average.Second, <strong>the</strong> guidepost principle has always contained a clear exceptionfor wage changes that serve an economic function by assisting in <strong>the</strong> reallocation<strong>of</strong> labor toward shortage occupations and industries. Thus, forexample, no complaint has ever been made in <strong>the</strong> name <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> guidepostswith respect to <strong>the</strong> large wage increases recently received by nurses.Indeed, in a high-employment economy, <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> differentialwage changes as an instrument <strong>of</strong> labor reallocation is greatly increased,and, this exception is more important today than in earlier years. However,<strong>the</strong> Council suggests that, as a general principle, an exception to <strong>the</strong>guideposts for workers in a shortage occupation should be claimed onlywhere <strong>the</strong> union involved stands ready to lift every artificial barrier toentry into <strong>the</strong> occupation, and to cooperate fully in public and privateefforts to train whatever numbers <strong>of</strong> workers may desire to enter <strong>the</strong> occupation.Moreover, as indicated in Chapter 2, <strong>the</strong> remaining labor shortagesthis year will be concentrated in unorganized pr<strong>of</strong>essional and technicaloccupations.O<strong>the</strong>r exceptions have frequently been proposed for incorporation ina national wage policy.One such proposal is to allow for <strong>the</strong> narrowing <strong>of</strong> differentials betweenwage rates paid in different industries or by different employers for similarwork—<strong>the</strong> so-called issue <strong>of</strong> "comparable wages." To <strong>the</strong> extent that suchdifferentials may interfere with a rational allocation <strong>of</strong> labor, <strong>the</strong>ir correctionis already encouraged by <strong>the</strong> exception just discussed.The public interest obviously requires that wage settlements pay appropriateattention to factors <strong>of</strong> comparability. But it cannot accept inflationarysettlements ever)' time this justification is alleged.At least within a single labor market area, it is surely desirable that workersin occupations requiring similar training, skill, education, and responsibilityshould be paid <strong>the</strong> same wage. This is less obvious as between labor markets.Even within labor markets, some wage differentials may reflect <strong>the</strong> factthat one employer finds it worthwhile to pay above-average rates in orderto insure low turnover, good morale, and greater selectivity in hiring, whileano<strong>the</strong>r prefers to pay lower rates and forego <strong>the</strong>se advantages.130


It is probably true, on <strong>the</strong> whole, that <strong>the</strong> dispersion <strong>of</strong> wages for similarwork by similar workers is larger than it should be from <strong>the</strong> point <strong>of</strong> view <strong>of</strong>ei<strong>the</strong>r efficiency or equity. But <strong>the</strong> wage comparisons made in collectivebargaining disputes <strong>of</strong>ten have little or no relevance ei<strong>the</strong>r to resource allocationor to equity. Very <strong>of</strong>ten <strong>the</strong> wage comparisons in collective bargainingare only part <strong>of</strong> a game <strong>of</strong> follow-<strong>the</strong>-leader which, at best, is irrelevantto resource allocation and, at worst, speeds up a wage-price spiral.Many recent instances in which outsized wage agreements have emergedfrom collective bargaining—based on claims that such increases were necessaryin order to achieve wage comparability—have created more problems<strong>of</strong> inequity and inefficiency than <strong>the</strong>y have resolved. Meaningfulwage comparisons should be made not only with wages that are higherbut also with those that are lower. O<strong>the</strong>rwise, wage increases to achievec 'comparability" may actually reduce it. Unions can always find somegroup <strong>of</strong> workers more highly paid than <strong>the</strong>y—whe<strong>the</strong>r or not all o<strong>the</strong>rconditions are similar. If all corrections <strong>of</strong> such "inequities" are upward,labor cost inflation is inevitable.One recent important collective bargaining dispute produced a highlyinflationary uniform percentage increase for <strong>the</strong> entire work force involved.The justification was that an increase <strong>of</strong> this magnitude was necessaryto correct what may have been genuine disparity between <strong>the</strong> wages<strong>of</strong> a small group <strong>of</strong> specialized workers and similar workers in o<strong>the</strong>r employments.The mediation committee which recommended <strong>the</strong> settlementrecognized that, for <strong>the</strong> great majority <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> work force involved, wagerates were already as high as or, higher than those for comparable workers.But <strong>the</strong>y could not recommend des#oying <strong>the</strong> customary relationshipbetween <strong>the</strong> wages <strong>of</strong> those workers for whom <strong>the</strong> disparity wasfound to exist and <strong>the</strong> wages <strong>of</strong> all o<strong>the</strong>r members <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> work force.This is a clear recipe for inflation.Ano<strong>the</strong>r exception frequently urged is that, in industries with rapid productivitygains, wages should rise faster than <strong>the</strong> average. If such an exceptionwere made, it would necessarily impart an inflationary bias to <strong>the</strong>system—for no one argues that wages will or should rise less rapidly or notat all in industries with little or no productivity gain.It is clearly in <strong>the</strong> public interest for unit labor costs and prices to fall inindustries with relatively high productivity gains. In <strong>the</strong> long run, fallingunit labor costs do result in falling prices (except where <strong>the</strong>re are <strong>of</strong>fsettingincreases in o<strong>the</strong>r costs). But <strong>the</strong> long run may be too long for labor's and<strong>the</strong> public's patience. And sometimes <strong>the</strong> very factors that produce fallingcosts may work against price reduction. For example, <strong>the</strong> industries inwhich labor costs are falling are <strong>of</strong>ten those in which demand, and thus production,is expanding most rapidly—a situation which weakens ra<strong>the</strong>r thanstreng<strong>the</strong>ns <strong>the</strong> competitive forces driving down prices.If <strong>the</strong>re is a long lag between a reduction in labor costs and a reductionin prices, it is difficult to make a convincing case that high wage settlements


in industries with high productivity growth are not in <strong>the</strong> public interest.As <strong>the</strong> 1964 <strong>Report</strong> (p. 120) put it:Such circumstances pose a most unattractive dilemma from <strong>the</strong> viewpoint<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> public interest. On <strong>the</strong> one hand, extra increases in wages or fringebenefits might tend to spread to o<strong>the</strong>r industries, creating a general cost-pushfrom <strong>the</strong> wage side. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, <strong>the</strong>re is no justification, on ei<strong>the</strong>reconomic or equity grounds, for distributing above-average gains in productivityexclusively through <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its channel. The real way out <strong>of</strong> thisdilemma is for <strong>the</strong> firms involved to remove its cause by reducing prices.That statement is as important in 1967 as it was in 1964. Indeed, it formsone <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> most significant elements <strong>of</strong> a national price policy for 1967.Ano<strong>the</strong>r <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> reasons given for an exception to <strong>the</strong> wage guidepost isability to pay. In practice, this refers to <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> bargainingemployers. Ability-to-pay considerations are, <strong>of</strong> course, <strong>of</strong>ten related to<strong>the</strong> industry's own productivity trend. Industries with rapid productivitygains, falling labor costs, and stable prices are industries in which pr<strong>of</strong>its haverisen.But ability-to-pay considerations arise independently in ano<strong>the</strong>r context.In any period <strong>of</strong> rapid expansion toward full utilization, pr<strong>of</strong>its inevitablyrise faster than total employee income—just as pr<strong>of</strong>its fall more rapidly whenutilization rates decline. The past 5 years have been such a period <strong>of</strong> risingpr<strong>of</strong>its. It is not surprising that trade unions seek to share in <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its generatedby prosperity.The record shows, however, that attempts on <strong>the</strong> part <strong>of</strong> unions to redistributeincome from pr<strong>of</strong>its to wages through excessive wage increasesin high-pr<strong>of</strong>it industries results primarily in higher prices in those industries.When this happens, <strong>the</strong> effect is to redistribute real income from <strong>the</strong> rest<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> community—who are mostly o<strong>the</strong>r wage earners—to <strong>the</strong> workers inquestion, with very little redistribution from pr<strong>of</strong>its to wages.To avoid a wage-price spiral it is <strong>the</strong>refore essential that firms withdiscretion over prices—and particularly those with unusually high pr<strong>of</strong>its—pursue price policies which will not invite excessive wage demands.Price Policy for 1967The foregoing discussion (and that <strong>of</strong> Chapter 2) has indicated <strong>the</strong>essential character <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> problems which businesses with pricing discretionwill face in 1967:(1) Wage contracts newly negotiated in 1967 will tend to raise <strong>the</strong> unitlabor costs <strong>of</strong> many firms and industries.(2) Never<strong>the</strong>less, many important industries will continue to operate in1967 under labor contracts negotiated in 1965 or 1966, which <strong>of</strong>ten will beconsistent with declining unit labor costs.(3) Although <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> purchased industrial products may frequentlybe higher in 1967 than in 1966, <strong>the</strong>^purchase cost <strong>of</strong> some raw materialswill be lower.132


(4) Many firms in 1967 will be using new and modern capital equipmentinstalled during <strong>the</strong> past year, and will be under less pressure to operatemarginal units. Often this will involve substantially lower costs.In short, <strong>the</strong> cost picture for price setters in 1967 will continue to be amixed one.Although average pr<strong>of</strong>it margins <strong>of</strong> manufacturers declined in <strong>the</strong> secondhalf <strong>of</strong> 1966, <strong>the</strong>y were higher for <strong>the</strong> entire year—at least as a percentage<strong>of</strong> equity—than in any prior year since <strong>the</strong> highly inflationary year <strong>of</strong> 1950.In <strong>the</strong> past, pr<strong>of</strong>it rates like those recorded in 1966 endured only for briefperiods. Pr<strong>of</strong>its rose rapidly in cyclical expansions. But as <strong>the</strong> economyreached and quickly passed a cyclical peak, reductions in capacity utilizationretarded <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> productivity and intensified competitive pressures,with a resulting erosion <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it margins. If public and private policiesnow succeed in maintaining a steadily expanding economy, it followsthat <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it margins which were feasible only in <strong>the</strong> boom stage <strong>of</strong> aboom-bust economy—and <strong>the</strong>refore may have been appropriate in thatstage—are inappropriate in a steadily prosperous economy.Once firms can become accustomed to operating in a more stable environment,<strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it margins which <strong>the</strong>y now seek to achieve in periods <strong>of</strong> highutilization can be reduced, as no longer necessary to make up for <strong>the</strong> low andfrequently inadequate pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>of</strong> periods <strong>of</strong> slack and recession. In fact,pr<strong>of</strong>it margins not only should be lower than in <strong>the</strong> boom phase <strong>of</strong> a cyclicaleconomy, but should be reduced on <strong>the</strong> average because operations in suchan environment carry lesser risk.It is true that an adjustment to lower pr<strong>of</strong>it margins may be feasible andappropriate only if steady economic advance can be maintained. But it isequally true that such an adjustment <strong>of</strong> margins may itself be required if asteadily high employment economy is to be maintained.In an economy which grows steadily but does not outrun <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong>capacity, <strong>the</strong>re will be vigorous competition, and, ultimately, pr<strong>of</strong>it marginsin most industries should seek an appropriate level. But competitive pressureswork slowly. In industries where a small number <strong>of</strong> leading firmspossess strong market power, <strong>the</strong>y work very slowly indeed. Firms in thoseindustries in which market power, combined with strong demand, has pushedpr<strong>of</strong>it margins to record levels, have a special responsibility in price-makingat this critical time.If, in 1967, firms with discretion as to <strong>the</strong>ir prices should follow pricingpolicies which even maintain present margins, <strong>the</strong> opportunity for a significantlyimproved price record will be compromised. It would speed up<strong>the</strong> rise in living costs, and it would again pose inviting targets for inflationarywage demands by unions.To assume steady movement toward price stability in 1967, <strong>the</strong> publicinterest requires that producers absorb cost increases to <strong>the</strong> maximum extentfeasible, and take advantage <strong>of</strong> every opportunity to lower prices.133


In so doing, <strong>the</strong>y will make an important contribution to streng<strong>the</strong>ningAmerica's international competitive position and to a climate that willpermit <strong>the</strong> economy to maintain <strong>the</strong> forward momentum which will preserveand enlarge <strong>the</strong> gains <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> past 6 years <strong>of</strong> rewarding prosperity.134


Chapter 4Selected Uses <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> GrowthAGREAT FINANCIER is said to have remarked that compoundinterest is <strong>the</strong> eighth wonder <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> world. No doubt he was referringto its remarkable properties in enhancing private fortunes. However, thoseconcerned with national policies for economic growth have also becomeaware <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> power <strong>of</strong> compound interest. If <strong>the</strong> American economy continuesto grow at 4 percent a year, output will double in 18 years, triple in28, quadruple in 35. If that potential is wisely and efficiently shared amongcompeting uses, great advances in <strong>the</strong> economic well-being <strong>of</strong> all Americansare assured.Literally billions <strong>of</strong> private and public decisions determine <strong>the</strong> distribution<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> growing gross national product (GNP) among consumption, investment,and Government purchases, and—within each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se categories—among <strong>the</strong> myriad <strong>of</strong> individual goods and services <strong>the</strong> economy can provide.Consumption decisions <strong>of</strong> households and <strong>the</strong> investment decisions <strong>of</strong>business firms determine <strong>the</strong> uses <strong>of</strong> output in <strong>the</strong> private sector. But <strong>the</strong>sedecisions are inevitably affected by public policies. Monetary and creditpolicies and changes in tax rates and tax incentives restrain or encourageconsumer and business outlays and influence <strong>the</strong>ir composition.The budget-making process at Federal, State, and local levels determines<strong>the</strong> share <strong>of</strong> output used to meet public needs. Taxes and public spendingrepresent a substantial share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> national product. Moreover, in agrowing economy with given tax rates, tax revenues move upward stronglyover time and call for continued decisions on increases in public expenditures,tax reductions, and debt management. Public policy cannot beneutral in its impact on <strong>the</strong> allocation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> gains from economic growth.How <strong>the</strong>se gains should be distributed must be squarely faced as an issue <strong>of</strong>public policy.PRIVATE AND PUBLIC GOODSHouseholds directly purchase <strong>the</strong> greater part <strong>of</strong> our national outputto meet <strong>the</strong>ir wants and needs as consumers. Personal consumption expendituresnow constitute 63 percent <strong>of</strong> GNP. The share has been as low as52 percent in World War II and as high as 83 percent in <strong>the</strong> depression135


year 1932, but has recently been relatively stable. Most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> futureincrease in output will surely take <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> more goods and services forconsumers.CONSUMER CHOICEGrowing incomes will enable households to enjoy continuing increases in<strong>the</strong>ir standards <strong>of</strong> living. For those families which are now poor, higherincomes will mean more <strong>of</strong> those types <strong>of</strong> goods and services which mostAmericans now regard as necessities—adequate and varied diets, sufficien<strong>the</strong>alth care, satisfactory housing, a good education for <strong>the</strong>ir children.Even for Americans well above <strong>the</strong> poverty line, a significant share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>growth in incomes will be devoted to <strong>the</strong>se basic items. With higher incomes,<strong>the</strong> proportion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> budget spent for various types <strong>of</strong> goods shifts in fairlypredictable ways—toward consumer durable goods, travel, recreation, ando<strong>the</strong>r leisure-time activities. Rising incomes provide for more freedom, moresecurity, more comforts, more cultural opportunity, and more variety in life,permitting <strong>the</strong> greater fulfillment <strong>of</strong> personal aspirations.EXTERNAL EFFECTSThe buyer receives satisfaction from most purchases he makes, and hepays <strong>the</strong> cost. Society as a whole has no important concern about whe<strong>the</strong>r<strong>the</strong> individual chooses to eat more steak and to buy fewer new clo<strong>the</strong>s,or <strong>the</strong> reverse. But <strong>the</strong>re are many instances in which one man's consumptionmay affect his neighbors significantly. In <strong>the</strong> technical language <strong>of</strong>economists, many economic actions have important "external effects" onpersons who are not decision-makers in <strong>the</strong> transaction and whose interestsare not normally reflected. Indeed, <strong>the</strong>se actions are increasing in numberas <strong>the</strong> size, complexity, and interdependence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> American economyincreases.An extreme form <strong>of</strong> external effects occurs in <strong>the</strong> category <strong>of</strong> commoditiescalled "public goods." Once created, <strong>the</strong>ir use cannot be effectively limitedto a group <strong>of</strong> paying customers or subscribers. A health program to eradicatecommunicable diseases is an example <strong>of</strong> a public good. Police protectionand national defense are o<strong>the</strong>r examples—where everyone can benefitwithout reducing benefits available to o<strong>the</strong>rs. Since no one can be excludedfrom <strong>the</strong> enjoyment <strong>of</strong> public goods, each person would be temptedto let his neighbor pay for <strong>the</strong>m, while he spent his own income on goodswhich he enjoys exclusively. For this reason, decisions to supply publicgoods are everywhere made collectively and paid for collectively by taxes.In less extreme, but more typical cases <strong>of</strong> external effects, private decisionswould lead to some production and consumption <strong>of</strong> goods, but not <strong>the</strong>right amount from <strong>the</strong> standpoint <strong>of</strong> society as a whole. The modernization<strong>of</strong> one house may help to upgrade an entire block, but might not be undertakenif <strong>the</strong> homeowner had to pay <strong>the</strong> full cost. The smoke from one136


man's chimney can spread soot far and wide—and might be stopped if <strong>the</strong>originator paid <strong>the</strong> full costs he is imposing on o<strong>the</strong>rs. Such cases <strong>of</strong> externalbenefits, which extend to roads, parks, and education, are important reasonsfor <strong>the</strong> growing responsibilities <strong>of</strong> Federal, State, and local governments.Ano<strong>the</strong>r part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se responsibilities stems from a social concern forequality <strong>of</strong> opportunity and relief <strong>of</strong> human misery. There is growingrecognition that many Americans, due to accident <strong>of</strong> birth or circumstance,do not share in <strong>the</strong> blessings <strong>of</strong> a rich society, have little opportunity <strong>of</strong> eversharing, and moreover, may well see <strong>the</strong>ir children, too, denied an opportunityto compete on an equal footing. Programs for income maintenance,health, education, and cities reflect this recognition and social concern, aswell as awareness <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> external costs and benefits.In meeting social responsibilities <strong>of</strong> all kinds, <strong>the</strong>re is <strong>of</strong>ten a choicebetween public production and public encouragement to private productionthrough subsidies, regulation, or financial aids to purchasers. Forexample, a comprehensive medical insurance system may reduce <strong>the</strong>need for public hospitals for <strong>the</strong> poor. Decisions in such matters have beenmade pragmatically; many are perhaps accidents <strong>of</strong> history. The postalservice is nationalized while telephone and telegraph service is provided byregulated private enterprise. Yet <strong>the</strong>se decisions have produced viableresults. In contrast with experience abroad and our own experience inprevious generations, <strong>the</strong>re is no major ideological battle in <strong>the</strong> United Statestoday over <strong>the</strong> scope <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Government sector. Public policy now faces upto questions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Government-private mix in a flexible manner, endeavoringto meet <strong>the</strong> aspirations <strong>of</strong> our citizenry with greatest efficiency whilemaintaining an appropriate preference for decentralization in decisionmaking.The increased wealth <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> United States permits us to face directly<strong>the</strong> problems <strong>of</strong> poverty, lack <strong>of</strong> education, ill health, and urban decay asnational issues requiring a coordinated policy effort. Many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>seproblems can be solved most efficiently by State and local governments if<strong>the</strong>y have <strong>the</strong> resources. O<strong>the</strong>r problems require national policies. Thepace <strong>of</strong> progress in meeting <strong>the</strong>m will be held back as long as our commitmentsin Vietnam absorb a substantial share <strong>of</strong> our economic growth.But, even in this period, progress can and will be made. And, when <strong>the</strong>welcome opportunities <strong>of</strong> peace arise, we will be ready to intensify ourefforts to build a better America.The following sections <strong>of</strong> this chapter discuss selected areas in which<strong>the</strong> provision <strong>of</strong> public goods, <strong>the</strong> external effects <strong>of</strong> economic decisions, or<strong>the</strong> achievement <strong>of</strong> humanitarian goals will absorb part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> additionaloutput which constitutes economic growth. The conquest <strong>of</strong> poverty,improvements in education, better health, and <strong>the</strong> rebuilding <strong>of</strong> Americancities are expensive. They will make substantial claims even on our growing137


affluence. Choices will have to be made—not to solve one problem at <strong>the</strong>expense <strong>of</strong> ano<strong>the</strong>r, but ra<strong>the</strong>r to allocate resources in such a way as to permitbalanced progress on many fronts.INCOME MAINTENANCEPoverty in <strong>the</strong> United States today afflicts 32.7 million Americans directlyand every American indirectly. But poverty is curable, and <strong>the</strong> Nation isnow committed to using a share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> fruits <strong>of</strong> growth to stamp out thismalady.POVERTY AND WORKBy definition, <strong>the</strong> poor have incomes inadequate to provide even <strong>the</strong> basicessentials <strong>of</strong> a decent life in our society. A household is statistically classifiedas poor if its total money income falls below levels specified by <strong>the</strong> Social SecurityAdministration, currently $1,570 for an unrelated individual, $2,030for a couple, and $3,200 for a family <strong>of</strong> four. Obviously, any such statisticalclassification ignores such factors as assets, particular family needs, and<strong>the</strong> variability <strong>of</strong> income. But it helps to illuminate <strong>the</strong> extent and character<strong>of</strong> poverty.In <strong>the</strong> broadest sense, <strong>the</strong> poor comprise two general categories. Thefirst, but smaller, includes families headed by an able-bodied male breadwinnerwhose wages are low or whose employment is irregular. Amongnonwhite families in <strong>the</strong> South, even breadwinners holding full-time jobs<strong>of</strong>ten do not earn living wages (Table 19). For <strong>the</strong> entire Nation, however,only 6 percent <strong>of</strong> all families headed by a fully employed male workerwere below <strong>the</strong> poverty line in 1965, but this group includes 26 percent <strong>of</strong>all poor families. Large family size was a characteristic <strong>of</strong> many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>sehouseholds. Ano<strong>the</strong>r group—15 percent <strong>of</strong> all poor families—was headedby a chronically unemployed man or by one who worked only part-time.Poverty among families with able-bodied male breadwinners has declinedsubstantially in recent years. For example, improving nonfarm job opportunities,which facilitated migration from <strong>the</strong> farm, also meant a welcomemigration out <strong>of</strong> poverty for many rural families. The number <strong>of</strong>poor farm households fell by 53 percent between 1959 and 1965 (Table 20)and represented only 6 percent <strong>of</strong> all poor households in 1965, althoughsome <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> formerly poor farm families who acquired urban addressesremained poor.But most poor families are headed by persons who cannot or should notbe in <strong>the</strong> labor force, at least on a full-time basis. The aged, <strong>the</strong> familyconsisting <strong>of</strong> a female head with children, and <strong>the</strong> disabled are increasinglybecoming <strong>the</strong> dominant groups <strong>of</strong> "hard-core poor," accounting for abouthalf <strong>of</strong> all poor families in 1965. Rapid economic growth and full employ-138


TABLE 19.—The poor and <strong>the</strong>ir work experience, 1965 *Work experience <strong>of</strong> head <strong>of</strong> householdPoor households(millions) %Number(millions)Poor familiesIncidence <strong>of</strong>poverty(percent) 3MaleheadFemaleheadMaleheadFemaleheadMaleheadFemaleheadTotal.Aged (65 years and over).All o<strong>the</strong>r...... ...Did not work in 1965..Ill or disabledO<strong>the</strong>r reasonsWorked at part-time jobs.Worked at full-time jobsEmployed 39 weeks or less...Employed 40-49 weeksEmployed 50 weeks or more.0-3 children4 or more children.SouthsWhite*Nonwhite "..Rest <strong>of</strong> country«6.11.84.3.53.0.41.81.0.75.4 4.82.4 1.23.0 3.61.5 .5.2 .31.3 .2.5 .41.0 2.7.4 .6.1 .4.4 1.7.1 1.0.1 .7.2 .9.1 .5.1 .41.91.5.8.1.811372940664423492415116524115110White«Nonwhite8221 Numbers in this table are based on <strong>the</strong> Current Population Survey. An enlarged survey <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor,now in progress, may show somewhat different results due to sampling error and <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> different interviewingtechniques.2 Households are defined here as <strong>the</strong> total <strong>of</strong> families and unrelated individuals.3 Poor families as percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total number <strong>of</strong> families in <strong>the</strong> category.* Percent not shown because <strong>of</strong> small number <strong>of</strong> families.« Estimated by Department <strong>of</strong> Health, Education, and Welfare.«Less than 50,000.NOTE.—Poverty is defined by <strong>the</strong> Social Security Administration poverty-income standard; it takesinto account family size, composition, and place <strong>of</strong> residence.Detail will not necessarily add to totals because <strong>of</strong> rounding.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce and Department <strong>of</strong> Health, Education, and Welfare.ment can do little to solve <strong>the</strong>ir problems. For <strong>the</strong>m, cash benefits areessential.For those <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor who can work full time, economic growth and fullemployment will continue to erode poverty. But for <strong>the</strong>m, too, cashbenefits are required to alleviate <strong>the</strong> immediate rigors <strong>of</strong> poverty, while<strong>the</strong>y take training, while <strong>the</strong>y are being relocated, while <strong>the</strong>y seek andfind jobs.INCOME MAINTENANCE AND THE POORIncome maintenance programs financed by Federal, State, and localgovernments provide some support for millions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor. The poor,like o<strong>the</strong>rs, enjoy protection under major social insurance programs,such as Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance (OASDI),Health Insurance for <strong>the</strong> Aged, and Unemployment Insurance. Roughlyone-third <strong>of</strong> OASDI benefits, which totaled $18 billion in 1965, went139


TABLE 20.—Number <strong>of</strong> poor households and incidence <strong>of</strong> poverty, 1959, 1962,and 1965TotalCharacteristics <strong>of</strong> head <strong>of</strong> householdAged (65 years and over) 3WhiteMaleFemaleNonwhiteMale..Female.All o<strong>the</strong>r *FarmAddendum:WhiteMaleFemaleNonwhiteMaleFemaleNonfarmWhiteMaleFemale_ __-NonwhiteMale .FemalePoverty income gap 7Number <strong>of</strong> poor households(millions)»195913.43.93.51.61.9.4.2.29.41.51.11.0.1.4.4.18.05.73.52.22.21.31.0196212.63.83.31.41.9.4.2.28.9.9.7.6.1.2.27.95.53.52.02.41.31.0Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars196511.53.83.41.32.1.5.2.37.6.7.5.4.1.2.27.04.92.92.02.01.1.913.7 12.8 8 11.01959Incidence <strong>of</strong> poverty(percent) 247 47 3738 38 2968 68 581962 196524492241193947 39 3736 28 2463 56 5573 64 6566 54 5475827818201531402434 25 1832 24 1757 39 4086861881791776761515 14 1210 10 837 34 30Percent <strong>of</strong> GNP2.8 2.3 | 81.61 Households are denned here as <strong>the</strong> total <strong>of</strong> families and unrelated individuals..2 Poor households as percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total number <strong>of</strong> households in <strong>the</strong> category.3 Includes only one- and two-person households with head aged 65 years and over.4 Includes all households headed by a person under 65 years <strong>of</strong> age and families <strong>of</strong> three or more headedby an aged person.»Less than 50,000.e Percent not shown because <strong>of</strong> small number <strong>of</strong> households.7 The poverty income gap is <strong>the</strong> amount which would raise money income <strong>of</strong> all poor households over <strong>the</strong>poverty threshold.s Preliminary.NOTE.—Poverty is denned by <strong>the</strong> Social Security Administration poverty-income standard; it takes intoaccount family size, composition, and place <strong>of</strong> residence. Poverty-income lines are adjusted to take account<strong>of</strong> price changes during <strong>the</strong> period.Detail will not necessarily add to totals because <strong>of</strong> rounding.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce and Department <strong>of</strong> Health, Education, and Welfare.to <strong>the</strong> poor and ano<strong>the</strong>r two-fifths went to households which o<strong>the</strong>rwisewould have been poor. O<strong>the</strong>r programs, such as Public Assistance, FoodStamps, and Commodity Distribution, provide most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir benefits to <strong>the</strong>poor. Expenditures under <strong>the</strong>se programs totaled nearly $7 billion in fiscalyear 1966.Public AssistanceThe major income maintenance program aimed directly at <strong>the</strong> poor isPublic Assistance. In many respects, this program still reflects conditionsthat surrounded its adoption in <strong>the</strong> depression years <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1930's, when<strong>President</strong> Roosevelt saw one-third <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Nation as economically deprived.140


At that time it was designed to make cash payments to those who were unemployableand unable to help <strong>the</strong>mselves because <strong>of</strong> identifiable family orpersonal characteristics, including old age, death or absence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> breadwinner,disability, and blindness. But <strong>the</strong> program has never been adequate,and with <strong>the</strong> Nation's growing affluence its shortcomings are even lesstolerable.The States pay 41 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> costs <strong>of</strong> Public Assistance, and <strong>the</strong>y establishstandards <strong>of</strong> eligibility. In response to general financial pressures,many States have cut costs by establishing low standards <strong>of</strong> need and imposingstringent requirements relating to length <strong>of</strong> residence, o<strong>the</strong>r incomeand assets, and relatives' responsibility. Less than half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor fall within<strong>the</strong> Public Assistance categories; as a result <strong>of</strong> State eligibility requirements,only 22 percent actually receive any help; and for those on <strong>the</strong> rolls actualpayments typically fall far below need even as defined by <strong>the</strong> State itself.One <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Public Assistance programs, Aid to Families with DependentChildren (AFDG) can actually promote family dissolution. Because it excludesfamilies in which <strong>the</strong>re is an employed (or in some States, employable)adult male, a man unable to provide adequately for his wife and childrencan make <strong>the</strong>m eligible for cash payments only by deserting <strong>the</strong>m. TheUnemployed Parent Program under AFDC, introduced in 1962 and now inoperation in 21 States, <strong>the</strong>refore represents a gratifying step toward improving<strong>the</strong> present Public Assistance system.However, o<strong>the</strong>r problems with Public Assistance remain. For example,some <strong>of</strong> those who receive aid may be discouraged from helping <strong>the</strong>mselves.The cash payments are intended for those with no earning capacity andare curtailed to <strong>the</strong> extent that recipients have earnings. While relativelyfew recipients <strong>of</strong> Public Assistance can work, some mo<strong>the</strong>rs with dependentschool-age children and most fa<strong>the</strong>rs under <strong>the</strong> Unemployed Parent program,who might supplement <strong>the</strong>ir benefits with earnings, are discouragedfrom making <strong>the</strong> effort by knowledge that <strong>the</strong>ir assistance payments will bereduced one dollar for every dollar <strong>of</strong> earnings.The <strong>President</strong> is proposing important amendments to <strong>the</strong> Public Assistancesystem this year. They would require each State, as a condition for Federalsupport, to make assistance payments at least sufficient to bring householdsup to <strong>the</strong> needs standards which <strong>the</strong> State has established and toupdate <strong>the</strong>se standards as conditions change. The proposed legislationwould also alter <strong>the</strong> payment formulas to encourage self-support.The categories <strong>of</strong> persons eligible for aid under Public Assistance were setup in <strong>the</strong> 1930's. At that time, poverty was so extensive that benefits couldbe provided only to those obviously unable to support <strong>the</strong>mselves.But <strong>the</strong>se categories no longer seem adequate for a rich and prosperoussociety. In particular, it is necessary to consider <strong>the</strong> plight <strong>of</strong> one group excludedfrom virtually all existing programs—<strong>the</strong> 4 million poor households240-782 0—67 10141


headed by an able-bodied male under 65 who is, never<strong>the</strong>less, an inadequatebreadwinner. In <strong>the</strong> longer run, education, training, health and rehabilitationservices, counseling, employment information, and o<strong>the</strong>r supportiveservices are <strong>the</strong> key escape routes from poverty for potential full-time workerswith currently inadequate earning capacity. In <strong>the</strong> interim, ample benefitsto families with children have particular priority because <strong>the</strong>y can help toend <strong>the</strong> poverty cycle in which blighted environment denies poor children<strong>the</strong> skills and <strong>the</strong> attitudes <strong>the</strong>y need to break out <strong>of</strong> poverty as adults.Mo<strong>the</strong>rs with dependent children have particular needs for day-care schools,family management education, and transportation. Special programs, keyedto special problems, can reinforce a more general program <strong>of</strong> cash paymentsbased on need.TOWARD IMPROVED INCOME MAINTENANCE FOR THE POORIdeally, an income maintenance system should provide benefits on <strong>the</strong>basis <strong>of</strong> need, without degrading means tests, while preserving incentivesfor self help. These goals could be achieved through broadening<strong>the</strong> Public Assistance program or through new techniques, such as a minimumincome allowance or negative income tax. Much public attentionrecently has been focused on methods <strong>of</strong> guaranteeing a minimumincome, perhaps sufficient to eliminate poverty altoge<strong>the</strong>r.In considering <strong>the</strong>se or any o<strong>the</strong>r new approaches, <strong>the</strong> question <strong>of</strong> incentiveshas to be faced squarely. The poor cannot be expected to workwithout pay, any more than can <strong>the</strong> rich. If sufficient cash support were<strong>of</strong>fered to raise each poor household's income to a fixed minimum, such as<strong>the</strong> poverty threshold, <strong>the</strong>n recipients would have no incentive to obtainoutside earnings up to <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> income guarantee. Every dollarearned would be <strong>of</strong>fset by a dollar <strong>of</strong> cash support lost. Indeed, somepersons whose incomes were only slightly above <strong>the</strong> poverty threshold mightfind it attractive to reduce <strong>the</strong>ir work effort and to receive cash benefits.Incentives for self help would thus be dulled. But if benefit payments werecut back by only a fraction <strong>of</strong> any additional outside earnings, some benefitswould be paid to families with total incomes above <strong>the</strong> poverty level, increasing<strong>the</strong> cost. There is an abundance <strong>of</strong> assertion and anecdote regarding <strong>the</strong>impact <strong>of</strong> work incentives on low-income Americans, but little real knowledge.The Office <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Opportunity and <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Health,Education, and Welfare are each planning to undertake some pilot studiesin <strong>the</strong> coming year.SOCIAL SECURITYUnder <strong>the</strong> Social Security Act <strong>of</strong> 1935 and successive amendments,spectacular advances have been made toward providing all Americans withbasic social insurance protection against loss <strong>of</strong> income due to old age andretirement, long-term disability, and joblessness. Most social insuranceprograms provide protection against <strong>the</strong>se designated risks for <strong>the</strong> whole142


population, not just for <strong>the</strong> poor. Old-Age Insurance under <strong>the</strong> SocialSecurity Act is <strong>the</strong> basic retirement system for nearly all Americans. Itinsures many Americans against <strong>the</strong> risk <strong>of</strong> poverty in <strong>the</strong>ir old age:30 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> aged would be in poverty but for Social Security. Never<strong>the</strong>less,nearly two-fifths <strong>of</strong> all aged remain poor. This proportion willdecline under existing law, since new retirees will have longer and higherwage histories which will entitle <strong>the</strong>m to greater benefits.Fur<strong>the</strong>r liberalization in benefits—particularly in minimum benefits—canhasten <strong>the</strong> day when all Americans will be assured, upon retirement, <strong>of</strong> apension adequate to prevent poverty. Americans with incomes well abovepoverty levels also want and are willing to pay for increasing social insuranceprotection. Therefore, <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> is proposing a substantial liberalization<strong>of</strong> retirement benefits under Social Security, involving an increase in <strong>the</strong>minimum benefit from <strong>the</strong> present $44 a month to $70 a month, and a 15percent increase in all o<strong>the</strong>r benefits coupled with an increase in <strong>the</strong> earningsbase. Modernization and improvement <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal-State unemploymentinsurance system is also being proposed, in which extended benefits for <strong>the</strong>long-term unemployed will be coupled with automatic access to trainingand retraining and o<strong>the</strong>r rehabilitative services.In <strong>the</strong> last Congress, important amendments to <strong>the</strong> Social Security Actwere enacted to provide health protection for <strong>the</strong> aged through Medicareand to liberalize Social Security benefits. With enactment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new proposals,retirement, disability, and unemployment will have been transformedfor most Americans who have worked from risks which had to be borneunaided into contingencies against which a substantial measure <strong>of</strong> publicprotection is afforded.EDUCATIONOutlays for education have been rising by IOJ/2 percent a year for <strong>the</strong> lastdecade, making it one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> major U.S. growth industries. Direct costs forformal schooling in <strong>the</strong> current school year will total $49 billion (Table 21),nearly 6^2 percent <strong>of</strong> GNP.Education in <strong>the</strong> United States is both a public and a private undertaking.About three-fourths <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> costs <strong>of</strong> education are paid through governmentbudgets; tuition, endowments, and earnings <strong>of</strong> private institutions meet <strong>the</strong>remainder <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> bill. The Federal Government has long played a role incertain phases <strong>of</strong> education and has recently taken new large steps. Still,<strong>the</strong> bulk <strong>of</strong> public costs are borne by State and local governments.VALUE OF EDUCATIONEducation provides benefits both for <strong>the</strong> person receiving it and forsociety at large. For <strong>the</strong> individual, education produces both quantifiable143


TABLE 21.—Costs <strong>of</strong> formal education, 1966-67[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]ItemTotalElementaryandsecondaryeducationHighereducationDirect outlays-Student tuition and feesState governmentsLocal governmentsFederal GovernmentEndowment, charity, and earnings <strong>of</strong> institutions..48.83.614.715.76.18.732.010.715.32.32.816.82.74.0.43.85.9Indirect costs: Forgone student earnings i_.20 to 308 to 1212 to 18i Assuming 75 to 85 percent <strong>of</strong> students 16 years and over could find empoyment at from $1,000 to $4,500per annum depending on age and previous amount <strong>of</strong> schooling.NOTE.—Includes current and capital costs <strong>of</strong> public and private schools; excludes such items as on-<strong>the</strong>jobtraining and o<strong>the</strong>r education outside <strong>the</strong> school. Data are estimates for school year 1966-67.Detail will not necessarily add to totals because <strong>of</strong> rounding.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Health, Education, and Welfare and Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers.benefits, such as <strong>the</strong> chance for a higher paying job, and intangible rewards,such as <strong>the</strong> ability to live a fuller life in every sense. Some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se benefitsare private consumption; o<strong>the</strong>rs are "investment in human capital" which,like investments in machinery or plant, yield pr<strong>of</strong>its over a period <strong>of</strong> years.Increase in Earning PowerMany studies show that <strong>the</strong> quantity <strong>of</strong> education a person has receivedand his earning power are closely correlated. Of course, family incomeand family connections, and place <strong>of</strong> birth or residence—to say nothing <strong>of</strong>native ability and motivation—all tend to result in both higher educationalattainment and higher income. However, even after taking account <strong>of</strong>such factors, a dramatic story <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> net contribution <strong>of</strong> additional schoolingTABLE 22.Earnings <strong>of</strong> males, by years <strong>of</strong> school completed and o<strong>the</strong>r characteristics,1959 *Age group by years <strong>of</strong> school completedNorthWhite malesSouthNonwhite malesNorthSouth27-37 years <strong>of</strong> age:0-4 years8 years12 years16 years$3,1804,2275,3577,244$2,3613,6324,7826,554$3,0902,7463,6184,229$1,7172,0172,3093,15542-52 years <strong>of</strong> age:0-4 years8years12 years16 years3,7034,9286,2579,9752,7373,8955,7339,0062,8393,4694,2204,4771,8002,1992,7883,289i Unweighted average <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> earnings <strong>of</strong> single-age groups <strong>of</strong> 27, 32, and 37 years <strong>of</strong> age and 42, 47, and 52years <strong>of</strong> age, respectively.In computing <strong>the</strong> earnings, <strong>the</strong> following variables were held constant: rural or urban origin, size <strong>of</strong> family,marital status, 5-year residence in one State or not, and foreign or domestic born parents.Source: Calculated by Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers from tables in Giora Hanoch, Personal Earningsand Investment in Schooling, an unpublished Ph. D. dissertation, University <strong>of</strong> Chicago, December 1965.144


to earnings emerges. Table 22 records some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> results <strong>of</strong> a study <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>income and education <strong>of</strong> 34,180 employed males, classified according toa variety <strong>of</strong> personal characteristics. It shows, for example, that in 1959 awhite, male, high school graduate living in <strong>the</strong> North (aged 42 to 52) earned27 percent more than an elementary school graduate whose o<strong>the</strong>r measuredcharacteristics were identical, and a college graduate earned 59 percentmore than a high school graduate.Social BenefitsSome scholars have used evidence on private returns from education toestimate <strong>the</strong> returns on investments in education for <strong>the</strong> society as a whole.Some studies suggest that more than one-fifth <strong>of</strong> economic growth in <strong>the</strong>United States during <strong>the</strong> last three or four decades is attributable to increasesin <strong>the</strong> average educational attainment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> labor force, with perhaps ano<strong>the</strong>rone-fifth attributable to <strong>the</strong> general advance <strong>of</strong> knowledge.But many qualifications are required in any attempt to estimate <strong>the</strong> returnsto society from <strong>the</strong> benefits to individuals who receive education.For example, employers <strong>of</strong>ten use educational achievement as a kind <strong>of</strong> intelligenceor ability test in selecting employees—as a "ticket <strong>of</strong> admission"to better paying jobs. To this extent, education tends to yield higher returnsto <strong>the</strong> individual than to society.On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, education yields substantial external benefits whichwill not show up explicitly in <strong>the</strong> incomes <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> educated. Our economyand our society are built on <strong>the</strong> assumption <strong>of</strong> virtually universal literacy,which permits information to be transmitted immediately and directlyto everyone. Well-educated workers are more adaptable to changing economicconditions. Education can help to reduce antisocial and criminalbehavior. It is essential for political democracy.Education and <strong>the</strong> DisadvantagedIn <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> public expenditures to provide schooling at reducedprices to all persons, education—like o<strong>the</strong>r commodities—would be purchasedin largest quantities by <strong>the</strong> well-to-do. Since education in turnraises <strong>the</strong> capacity to earn, this would tend to perpetuate and aggravateincome inequality. Poverty would run through generations in avicious circle. The importance <strong>of</strong> education as a qualification for wellpayingjobs and <strong>the</strong> recognition that all Americans must be provided with<strong>the</strong> opportunity to join <strong>the</strong> economic mainstream toge<strong>the</strong>r emphasize <strong>the</strong>responsibility <strong>of</strong> governments to help finance education.Many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> underprivileged, particularly members <strong>of</strong> ethnic and racialminorities, have received less than <strong>the</strong>ir share <strong>of</strong> education. Measured byaverage years <strong>of</strong> schooling completed, nonwhites are today about where<strong>the</strong> white population was at least two decades ago. Some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> gaps145


are being reduced or even eliminated (Chart 13). Nearly all whites andnonwhites now complete elementary school, but <strong>the</strong> gap in high schoolcompletion rates remains large even among <strong>the</strong> 20-24 year old group.Moreover, nonwhites <strong>of</strong>ten receive not only less, but also poorer, formaleducation. Also, education acquired in pre-school years and outside <strong>the</strong>school is impaired when parents and companions suffer from educationalgaps. Hence, far larger efforts for <strong>the</strong> educationally disadvantaged arenecessary to bring about true equality <strong>of</strong> educational opportunity.It was in recognition <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> national importance <strong>of</strong> education that <strong>the</strong>Federal Government undertook a major new initiative with <strong>the</strong> Elementaryand Secondary Education Act <strong>of</strong> 1965, which provides financial help on <strong>the</strong>basis <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> children from low-income families. Under thisAct, <strong>the</strong> Federal Government is spending $1.2 billion in support <strong>of</strong> elementaryand secondary education in <strong>the</strong> current fiscal year, tripling <strong>the</strong>support it provided only 2 years ago. The "Head Start" program hasdemonstrated great capacity for benefiting disadvantaged, pre-school children.The Administration is <strong>the</strong>refore proposing that <strong>the</strong> benefits <strong>of</strong> thisprogram be extended by providing a follow-up program in <strong>the</strong> early elementarygrades.TRENDS IN DEMAND AND COSTSBetween 1956 and 1966, enrollment in full-time elementary and secondaryday schools in <strong>the</strong> United States increased by 33 percent, from 37.2 millionto 49.7 million. This sharp increase is attributable to <strong>the</strong> postwar spurtin birth rates and to greater school attendance by teenagers. Becauseroughly half <strong>of</strong> high school graduates continued on to college while <strong>the</strong>number <strong>of</strong> students graduating from high school rose sharply, college anduniversity enrollment doubled from 2.9 million in 1956 to 6.0 million in 1966.In <strong>the</strong> next decade, elementary and secondary school enrollments will increaseonly about one-fourth as much as in <strong>the</strong> past decade. Demand forcollege education, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, is expected to continue increasing rapidly,as <strong>the</strong> proportion <strong>of</strong> youths completing high school rises and as somewhatmore than half <strong>of</strong> high school graduates go to college. Projectionsfor <strong>the</strong> future also point to a continued very rapid rise in <strong>the</strong> fraction <strong>of</strong> laborforce entrants with a college education, which could reduce <strong>the</strong> returnsfrom higher education.Outlays per student-year <strong>of</strong> formal education at all levels have risen bynearly 90 percent during <strong>the</strong> past decade. The increase may reflect, inpart, improvements in <strong>the</strong> quality <strong>of</strong> education, but it also reflects highercosts <strong>of</strong> education. A major factor in <strong>the</strong> increase in costs has been <strong>the</strong>dramatic rise in pr<strong>of</strong>essional salaries at all levels, as increased demand forteachers outran <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> supply, especially since entry requirementsfor teachers were raised in many areas. Salaries rose substantially faster146


Chart 13Educational AttainmentPERCENT OF AGE GROUP*AT LEAST 8 YEARS OF ELEMENTARY SCHOOL402065 and Over 55-64PERCENT OF AGE GROUP*100AT LEAST 4 YEARS OF HIGH SCHOOL45-54 35-44 30-34AGE GROUP (YEARS)25-29 20-24802065 and Over 55-64 45-54 35-44 30-34AGE GROUP (YEARS)25-29 20-24*BASED ON AVERAGES OF MARCH DATA, 1964-66.SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE.147


than wages generally, and, in response, an unusually large number <strong>of</strong> formerelementary and secondary teachers returned to <strong>the</strong> classroom.Enrollments are expected to rise less rapidly over <strong>the</strong> next decade than<strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> college graduates available to teach in elementary and secondaryschools or than <strong>the</strong> number with advanced degrees available toteach in colleges and universities. However, it may take special efforts tomeet acute present shortages <strong>of</strong> teachers with specialized skills, such asnursery school instructors, teachers <strong>of</strong> remedial reading, and teachers <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>emotionally handicapped. In <strong>the</strong> recently initiated Teacher Corps, <strong>the</strong>Federal Government helps to support teams <strong>of</strong> specialized teachers who workin slum areas at <strong>the</strong> request <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> city. The expansion <strong>of</strong> special programs for<strong>the</strong> disadvantaged will require a major increase in <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> teachers in<strong>the</strong>se specialties.New MethodsLearning can be improved and <strong>the</strong> costs <strong>of</strong> education lowered by avariety <strong>of</strong> changes in techniques and technology: new curricula and methods<strong>of</strong> instruction including team teaching, more job specific and employmentoriented curricula; upgraded and more flexible school systems; greater application<strong>of</strong> learning <strong>the</strong>ory; incentive pay systems; full utilization <strong>of</strong> physicalplant, especially during nights and summers; and use <strong>of</strong> subpr<strong>of</strong>essionalaides to economize on pr<strong>of</strong>essional time. The Joint <strong>Economic</strong> Committeelast year surveyed pr<strong>of</strong>essional opinion on <strong>the</strong>se and o<strong>the</strong>r technologicaldevelopments. Educational television, teaching machines, computerizededucation, and programmed learning promise future educational breakthroughs—perhapsmore quality improvement than cost reduction for sometime. Many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> newer techniques remain to be tested in practice, andfur<strong>the</strong>r research is required.Forgone Earnings as a CostFrom <strong>the</strong> private point <strong>of</strong> view, forgone earnings (<strong>the</strong> sacrifice <strong>of</strong> opportunityto work full-time) are a significant part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> costs <strong>of</strong> secondary and,particularly, <strong>of</strong> higher education. Many potential students forgo educationbecause <strong>the</strong>y are unwilling or unable to defer careers, marriage, andpresent earnings. But society can afford to wait for <strong>the</strong> returns morepatiently than many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> young, especially <strong>the</strong> poor. Thus, <strong>the</strong> privatecosts <strong>of</strong> forgone earnings may exceed <strong>the</strong> social costs, <strong>the</strong>reby creating adeficiency <strong>of</strong> demand from a social point <strong>of</strong> view.College students could afford to wait more readily for future earnings if investmentin human capital could be financed as o<strong>the</strong>r forms <strong>of</strong> investment arefinanced, by borrowing against future earnings. In particular, students encounterproblems <strong>of</strong> raising sufficient funds without collateral. To fill gapsin private financial markets, a number <strong>of</strong> Federal and State student loan pro-148


grams have been initiated since 1958. A guaranteed student loan programrelying on private bank participation was provided in <strong>the</strong> Higher EducationAct <strong>of</strong> 1965, but its launching was slow, partly because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> tight moneyconditions <strong>of</strong> 1966. Additional steps are underway to streng<strong>the</strong>n and expandthis program. However, proposals for new financing techniques over<strong>the</strong> longer run need and deserve careful exploration. Some interestingproposals would provide for student loans with repayment scaled to <strong>the</strong>borrower's earnings after graduation.Over <strong>the</strong> next decade education will claim an increasing share <strong>of</strong> our growingincomes in a number <strong>of</strong> ways. First, throughout <strong>the</strong> society, averageeducational attainment is likely to increase. Second, significant efforts willbe made to improve <strong>the</strong> content and quality <strong>of</strong> education. Finally, societywill endeavor to assure that those disadvantaged groups now receiving education<strong>of</strong> below average quality and quantity should have full access to educationalopportunities. The distribution <strong>of</strong> responsibility between <strong>the</strong> publicand private sectors varies among <strong>the</strong>se areas. Private choices will largelydetermine <strong>the</strong> increases in average educational attainment, mainly throughgreater enrollments in colleges. Both private and public efforts will berequired to improve quality. The achievement <strong>of</strong> equality in educationalopportunity will be a top priority public responsibility.HEALTH CAREAmericans are demanding, receiving, and paying for more and bettermedical care every year, both as consumers and as taxpayers. Despite risingcosts, <strong>the</strong> Nation is demanding for everyone—whe<strong>the</strong>r he can personallyafford <strong>the</strong> costs or not—medical services which a few decades ago wereavailable only for <strong>the</strong> well-to-do.Health care has become one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> largest industries in <strong>the</strong> United States.It employs over 3 million people, more than do <strong>the</strong> steel, automobile, and aircraftmanufacturing industries combined. In 1965, total expenditures forhealth services, medical research, and new facilities totaled $40.8 billion,about 6 percent <strong>of</strong> GNP (Table 23). Public expenditures account for one-Total expendituresTABLE 23.—The Nation's health budget, 1965Expenditure categoryHospital and nursing home careServices <strong>of</strong> physicians, dentists, and o<strong>the</strong>r pr<strong>of</strong>essionalsDrugs and eyeglasses, and appliances. _ _ResearchConstructionAllo<strong>the</strong>r[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Totalexpendituresi40.814.712.76.01 52 03.8Consumers28.18.912.05.81.3FederalGovernment5.32.2.2.11.3.31.25.03.2.5.1.1.3.8State andlocalgovernmentsPhilanthropy1 Direct outlays for health care, including net cost <strong>of</strong> medical insurance. Excludes indirect costs <strong>of</strong> illness,such as income lost through illness.2 Less than $50 million.NOTE.—Detail will not necessarily add to totals because <strong>of</strong> rounding.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Health, Education, and Welfare.149o<strong>the</strong>r2.5.3.21.3.6


fourth <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total health budget <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Nation, just <strong>the</strong> reverse <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>situation in education.The methods by which health care is produced, distributed, and financedhave been changing rapidly. Home visits by physicians have become unusual.The total number <strong>of</strong> doctors has changed little, but <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong>specialists is increasing while that <strong>of</strong> general practitioners is falling. Moreservices are being dispensed through hospitals, where specialists are aided byelaborate equipment and auxiliary health technicians. Group practice isbecoming more common and medical insurance more important. Thesechanges will continue and will influence <strong>the</strong> quality and cost <strong>of</strong> medicalcare in <strong>the</strong> coming decade.DEMAND FOR MEDICAL CAREHealth research and <strong>the</strong> control <strong>of</strong> contagious disease are prime examples<strong>of</strong> public goods which would not be produced in adequate amounts withoutGovernment subsidy. Health care outlays which increase <strong>the</strong> Nation'sproductivity are investments in human capital—like outlays for education.But <strong>the</strong> major part <strong>of</strong> health care is a consumption item, reflecting <strong>the</strong> valueChart 14Age Adjusted Death RatesRATE PER 1,000 POPULATION3020AANONWHITE\10 —jWHITE^ ." * ^ i - -0J 1 1 111 J LL1 11 1 1 11 A (1 1 1 1 I_L±LLJ 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1NOTE.-AGE ADJUSTED DEATH RATES ARE RATES BY AGE, WEIGHTED BY THE 1940 AGE DISTRIBUTIONOF THE POPULATION. THE NUMBER OF STATES COVERED INCREASED FROM 10 STATES ANDTHE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA IN 1900 TO THE ENTIRE UNITED STATES IN 1933.SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH, EDUCATION, AND WELFARE.150


which individuals place on <strong>the</strong>ir own and o<strong>the</strong>rs' comfort and, indeed, on lifeitself. Like food, clothing, and shelter, some medical care is a necessity.But <strong>the</strong> notion <strong>of</strong> what is necessary changes as society becomes increasinglywealthy and technologically advanced. Medical research generates newcures or treatments <strong>of</strong> illnesses previously considered incurable, and thisadds fur<strong>the</strong>r to demands. And habits such as cigarette smoking, increaseduse <strong>of</strong> automobiles and pesticides, and growing urbanization and industrializationhave aggravated various health hazards.American performance in medical research has been outstanding. But<strong>the</strong> spread <strong>of</strong> knowledge and best practices has been slow and spotty. Thehealth care <strong>of</strong> sizable groups <strong>of</strong> Americans lags seriously behind that <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>majority. For example, <strong>the</strong> average life <strong>of</strong> nonwhites is 7 years shorter thanthat <strong>of</strong> whites; a newborn nonwhite child is nearly twice as likely to diein its first year as a newborn white child; and maternal mortality is fourtimes as high for nonwhites as for whites. There are also important disparitiesamong areas and regions. Low-income States have fewer doctorsand nurses than high-income States. Infant mortality in Mississippi is twicethat in Massachusetts. The poor and especially poor children receive lesshealth care than o<strong>the</strong>r Americans (Table 24).TABLE 24.—Physician and dental visits per year, by age and family income, 1963-64Family incomePhysician visits per year by age groupUnder 1515-64 years65 yearsand overDentalvisitsper yearUnder $2,000. ...$2,0Q0-$3,999____.$4,QG0-$6,999$7,000 and over..2.03.03.84.54.54.44.74.96.16.77.07.30.81.42.3NOTE.—Data are based on household interviews during <strong>the</strong> period July 1963 to June 1964.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Health, Education, and Welfare.Although U.S. health expenditures have risen steeply, mortality rates,which fell sharply in <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> century, did not decline significantlyduring <strong>the</strong> last decade (Chart 14). Moreover, our record with respect tolife expectancy and infant and maternal mortality lags behind that <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>radvanced countries, which have lower average incomes.Expansion <strong>of</strong> InsuranceThe expansion <strong>of</strong> medical insurance coverage has had a major impact on<strong>the</strong> demand for medical services. About 81 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> population under65 has some private hospital insurance coverage today, and 76 percent somesurgical coverage, compared with 9 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> population in 1940. In1965, about $8.7 billion—nearly one-third <strong>of</strong> consumer outlays for health—


was reimbursed by private medical insurance. However, most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> poorand many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> aged remained completely unprotected until last year.Legislation enacted in 1965 closed <strong>the</strong> biggest remaining gaps. With <strong>the</strong>enactment <strong>of</strong> Medicare, practically all <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> aged now have hospital insurance,and about 94 percent have insurance covering part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> doctors5 and o<strong>the</strong>r bills. Under <strong>the</strong> same legislation, medical payments underPublic Assistance are to be replaced by 1970 with new State programs <strong>of</strong>medical assistance for <strong>the</strong> poor under Medicaid.COST FACTORSThe costs <strong>of</strong> medical care, which have been rising about twice as rapidlyas average consumer prices over <strong>the</strong> past decade, jumped 6^2 percent during1966. The most rapid increases have been in hospital rates and, morerecently, in doctors' fees. Prices <strong>of</strong> drugs and medicines have not risen inrecent years. But nei<strong>the</strong>r have <strong>the</strong>y been reduced.The shift to hospital treatment, <strong>the</strong> increasing use <strong>of</strong> outpatient and emergencyfacilities, and <strong>the</strong> spread <strong>of</strong> group practice have enabled physiciansto use <strong>the</strong>ir time more efficiently. Prepaid medical care encourages earlydiagnosis and prompt treatment, which can save both money and lives. Newdrugs and medical practices, which shorten hospital stays, have partly <strong>of</strong>fset<strong>the</strong> increases in costs per hospital day. But hospital rates have soared aspatients have received more pr<strong>of</strong>essional services, more laboratory work,more drugs, more treatment by increasingly complex and costly equipment.In many areas, duplication <strong>of</strong> expensive and seldom used equipmentin several hospitals has contributed to rising costs. Labor requirements inhospitals have also risen sharply. The number <strong>of</strong> employees per patient hasalmost doubled in <strong>the</strong> last 20 years. Simultaneously, <strong>the</strong> wage gap betweenhospital workers and employees with corresponding skills elsewhere hasnarrowed in response to strong demands for workers in health occupations.PROSPECTS FOR THE COMING DECADEWith both costs and demand rising strongly, it seems likely that publicand private health expenditures, which rose from 4J4 percent to 6 percent<strong>of</strong> GNP in <strong>the</strong> past decade, will continue to command an increasing share<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Nation's resources. The bulk <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se outlays will be made by consumers,as <strong>the</strong>y have been in <strong>the</strong> past. Public expenditures will be particularlyimportant to break supply bottlenecks, and to close gaps in healthcare associated with poverty.Actions to Improve Health CareA serious obstacle to <strong>the</strong> improvement <strong>of</strong> health care is <strong>the</strong> shortage <strong>of</strong>doctors, nurses and o<strong>the</strong>r pr<strong>of</strong>essional health workers. The Public HealthService estimates that about one-half million pr<strong>of</strong>essional and subpr<strong>of</strong>essionalhealth workers are needed to bring standards throughout <strong>the</strong> countryup to those <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> nor<strong>the</strong>astern region. Several recent Federal legislative152


actions have been designed to help to meet <strong>the</strong> growing need. The HealthPr<strong>of</strong>essions Educational Assistance Act <strong>of</strong> 1963 extended grants for construction<strong>of</strong> medical and dental training facilities and initiated programs <strong>of</strong>student loans. Subsequent legislation expanded <strong>the</strong> scope <strong>of</strong> Federal assistanceto cover <strong>the</strong> training <strong>of</strong> nurses and subpr<strong>of</strong>essional health personnel,and added scholarships, assistance for school operations, and traineeshipsfor teachers in <strong>the</strong> health pr<strong>of</strong>essions. O<strong>the</strong>r general Federal manpowerprograms are also engaged in training subpr<strong>of</strong>essional health personnel.Last year, <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> appointed a National Commission on Health Manpower,due to report this June, to review remaining needs and to recommendfur<strong>the</strong>r remedies.These new directions in Federal programs are a much-needed complementto long-established support in <strong>the</strong> areas <strong>of</strong> research and construction. Under<strong>the</strong> Hill-Burton Act, enacted in 1946, more than $8.2 billion, including$2.6 billion <strong>of</strong> Federal funds, have been earmarked or spent for constructionor modernization <strong>of</strong> hospitals or extended care facilities with a capacity <strong>of</strong>358,000 beds.Although <strong>the</strong> shortage <strong>of</strong> nursing homes and o<strong>the</strong>r facilities for <strong>the</strong> agedis acute in some areas, a considerable number <strong>of</strong> vacancies exists in o<strong>the</strong>rareas. The development <strong>of</strong> needed additional centers for group medicalpractice will be assisted by legislation enacted in 1966 to permit Governmentmortgage insurance for group practice facilities.Considerable private and public effort is needed to hold down costs.Most health care is now dispensed ei<strong>the</strong>r in a physician's <strong>of</strong>fice or throughhospitals. Decreases in costs are possible through <strong>the</strong> increased use <strong>of</strong> clinicstations, outpatient facilities, diagnostic and treatment centers, supervisedhome care, and group practice. Careful study <strong>of</strong> new arrangements to makebetter use <strong>of</strong> scarce skills and facilities must be followed up by incentives formore efficient operation and distribution <strong>of</strong> health services. Hospital costaccounting and average cost pricing should be reexamined, particularly toassure that capital costs are rationally allocated over time and among uses.It is essential to avoid any tendency to control costs less carefully as a result<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> increasing scale <strong>of</strong> insurance and prepayment.As long as poverty persists, Federal, State, and local governments havea major commitment to help those unable to purchase <strong>the</strong>ir own care. Andprograms to promote <strong>the</strong> training <strong>of</strong> health personnel, support medical research,and improve health care systems impose particular responsibilitieson governments at all levels.CITIESAmericans have been flocking to urban areas since <strong>the</strong> RevolutionaryWar, when 95 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m earned <strong>the</strong>ir livelihood on <strong>the</strong> farm. Today,about two-thirds reside in metropolitan areas, roughly half in centralcities and half in suburbs. Almost all <strong>the</strong> growth in <strong>the</strong> total U.S. popu-


lation over <strong>the</strong> next decade will be in metropolitan areas and, as in <strong>the</strong>last decade, in suburbs ra<strong>the</strong>r than in central cities. But suburbanites alsohave a major stake in <strong>the</strong> quality <strong>of</strong> central cities, since <strong>the</strong>y continue to lookto <strong>the</strong> city for jobs, recreation, and culture,Throughout history, people and jobs have congregated in cities: <strong>the</strong> peoplecame in search <strong>of</strong> jobs; and <strong>the</strong> jobs came because employers found benefitsin urban location. Firms could pool costs with o<strong>the</strong>r firms and shareoverhead facilities. Specialized services were available to cater to <strong>the</strong>sporadic and unpredictable demands <strong>of</strong> a large number <strong>of</strong> enterprises.Firms could locate close to <strong>the</strong>ir suppliers' warehouses and could count onbeing able to meet unanticipated requirements on very short notice, <strong>the</strong>rebyeconomizing on inventories. It was highly advantageous to locate nearports and rail hubs, which in turn became virtually <strong>the</strong> center <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> city'seconomic organization.The city has lost some <strong>of</strong> its economic advantages, however. Many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>benefits from urban location arose from savings in transportation and communicationscosts, but <strong>the</strong> automobile and truck have drastically reduced <strong>the</strong>cost advantage <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> central city. The automobile increased congestion onold city streets, laid out for o<strong>the</strong>r transportation modes, and simultaneouslymade <strong>the</strong> location <strong>of</strong> factories and warehouses near beltways and interurbanhighway connections more advantageous. The development <strong>of</strong> moreefficient, faster communications media has also reduced <strong>the</strong> advantages <strong>of</strong>central city locations, especially for factories and goods-handling enterprises.The city has made vital contributions to economic growth in <strong>the</strong>past, and can continue to do so in <strong>the</strong> future. But <strong>the</strong> city needs modernizationand revitalization to become a more pleasant place in which to live andwork, and a more effective contributor to economic growth and productivity.Both aspects will involve private investment in housing and in plant andequipment, and a variety <strong>of</strong> public actions and expenditures.ELEMENTS OF THE URBAN PROBLEMDespite <strong>the</strong>ir earlier advantages and <strong>the</strong> continued preference <strong>of</strong> manyAmericans for urban life, cities today suffer from a wide range <strong>of</strong> economic,financial, and social problems.Cities have become congested and noisy. Traffic jams, packed subwaysand buses, and crowded airports are not only unpleasant but impose realeconomic costs in <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> wasted time, reduced efficiency, and, in somecases, personal injury and property damage. Noise causes distraction anddiscomfort. Crime and delinquency seem to be increasing. The problems<strong>of</strong> air pollution are becoming more and more acute. City water systems haveto remove increasing amounts <strong>of</strong> chemicals and wastes. Trash, junk, anddirt make life in cities both more expensive and less pleasant. The problems<strong>of</strong> poverty and unemployment among <strong>the</strong> young and disadvantaged are onoccasion brought to national attention through mass protest or social unrest.It is true that important progress is being made. Housing is better thanat any time in <strong>the</strong> past; communication is faster; city dwellers are healthier,154


TABLE 25.—Characteristics <strong>of</strong> population by areaCharacteristicAll areasMetropolitanCentralcitiesOutsidecentralcitiesXonmetropolitannonfarmFarmPopulation (millions) 1Percent <strong>of</strong> population:Children under 18 years <strong>of</strong> age 2A ged (65 years and over)Non whitePoorsMedian family income (dollars).191.536.49.411.817.16,56958.333.610.421.618.264.337.67.34.49.67,77257.137.610.69.422.45,54211.838.79.912.426.53,5581 Excludes inmates <strong>of</strong> institutions and all members <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> armed forces except those living <strong>of</strong>f post orwith <strong>the</strong>ir families on post. Metropolitan data exclude and farm data include <strong>the</strong> relatively few farmswithin Standard Metropolitan Statistical Areas.2 Never married children living in families.3 Poverty is defined by <strong>the</strong> Social Security Administration poverty-income standard; it takes into accountfamily size, composition, and pla'ce <strong>of</strong> residence.Note.—All data from Current Population Survey, March 1966, except median income from March 1965Survey.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce and Department <strong>of</strong> Health, Education, and Welfare.better educated, and wealthier. Incomes in cities are lower than in suburbsbut higher than in rural areas (Table 25). But concern about cities is growingbecause <strong>the</strong> standards <strong>of</strong> all Americans are rising and because <strong>the</strong> poorrightly insist on sharing access to <strong>the</strong> bounty that most Americans enjoy.In particular, <strong>the</strong> concentration <strong>of</strong> poverty among racial and linguistic minoritiesin congested areas leads to a problem which is considerably largerthan <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> its parts.Shifts in Jobs and PopulationAs industry has moved to <strong>the</strong> suburbs, so have job opportunities. In7 large metropolitan areas, for example, 975,000 new jobs became availablein <strong>the</strong> suburban ring in <strong>the</strong> period 1948-62, while <strong>the</strong> central cities<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> same metropolitan areas were gaining only 60,000 new jobs. Thecentral city gains were all in finance, insurance, real estate, and services.In manufacturing, <strong>the</strong> 7 central cities lost 150,000 jobs while <strong>the</strong>ir suburbanrings gained 250,000.Throughout <strong>the</strong> 19th century and <strong>the</strong> early part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 20th century, <strong>the</strong>growth <strong>of</strong> cities was spurred by immigration from abroad. The city provided<strong>the</strong> immigrant with his basic requirements at low cost—neighbors <strong>of</strong>similar origin, inexpensive housing near his job, schools, health services, andconvenient shopping. Since <strong>the</strong> 1920's immigration from abroad has beenreplaced by migration from rural areas. With flagging demand for lowskilledworkers, <strong>the</strong> cities have been relatively less successful with <strong>the</strong> newmigrants. And for <strong>the</strong> Negro migrant into <strong>the</strong> city, racial discriminationin housing and inadequate commuter transportation facilities have made itdifficult to follow <strong>the</strong> jobs to <strong>the</strong> suburbs.155


Urban BlightMeanwhile, <strong>the</strong> physical plants <strong>of</strong> cities have been aging and deteriorating.Because <strong>the</strong> very heart <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> city is still highly attractive to many kinds <strong>of</strong>enterprises, it frequently pays to tear down old buildings and replace <strong>the</strong>mwith new and more suitable structures. But, outside <strong>the</strong> very heart <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>city, private demand for replacement is inadequate to bring about <strong>the</strong>renewal <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> large nearby "gray areas" <strong>of</strong> housing which were yesterday's"suburbs" and are today's slums. Once blight begins, natural market forcesquicken <strong>the</strong> decay over a large area, as <strong>the</strong> deterioration <strong>of</strong> neighborhoodsweakens incentives for any one landlord to maintain <strong>the</strong> condition <strong>of</strong> hisproperty.Mismatch Between Costs and BenefitsUrban blight is only one example <strong>of</strong> how external effects <strong>of</strong> private actionsaffect <strong>the</strong> modern city. The man who drives to work considers that <strong>the</strong>convenience <strong>of</strong> driving his own car outweighs <strong>the</strong> inconvenience <strong>of</strong> congestion.But his reckoning neglects <strong>the</strong> costs he imposes on o<strong>the</strong>r commutersby increasing <strong>the</strong> congestion on <strong>the</strong> highway. In making locationdecisions, an industrialist will not necessarily consider <strong>the</strong> pollution <strong>of</strong> airand water which his factory causes. Should he decide to leave <strong>the</strong> city,his calculation will ignore <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> his departure on city revenues or<strong>the</strong> local rate <strong>of</strong> unemployment. In <strong>the</strong>se cases, private benefits exceedprivate costs; but because costs to <strong>the</strong> city, or even to society at large, arenot adequately considered in <strong>the</strong> decision, <strong>the</strong> action may be harmful.These discrepancies between private and social calculations distort choicesamong alternatives and constitute an important part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> cities' problems.All too <strong>of</strong>ten, <strong>the</strong> benefits accrue privately while <strong>the</strong> costs appear in a city'sbudget.City FinancesThe sheer proximity <strong>of</strong> large numbers <strong>of</strong> people brings special problemsand costs to city governments. Cities must supply services to commuters aswell as to residents: transportation, clean water, opportunities for recreation,and, perhaps most vital <strong>of</strong> all, economic opportunity. The city's inhabitantsdemand services from government that may be provided privately,or even be unnecessary, in <strong>the</strong> countryside. All <strong>the</strong>se requirements placeheavy burdens on public finance in <strong>the</strong> city. Thus, more is spent for governmentin cities than in o<strong>the</strong>r areas; on a per capita basis, medium-size citiesspend more than small ones, and large cities still more (Chart 15). Therelatively high per-capita tax base in cities is more than eaten up by highercosts and outlays.On <strong>the</strong> revenue side <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> ledger, <strong>the</strong>re are few taxes which cities caneffectively collect. Heavy property taxes can drive wealthier homeownersinto <strong>the</strong> suburbs. When applied to business property, such taxes can156


Chart 15Municipal Expenditures, Per CapitaDOLLARS400300-HEALTH, EDUCATION,AND WELFARE^ADMINISTRATION ANDCIVILIAN SAFETY-^Under 50- 100- 200- 300- 500- 1,00050 99 199 299 499 999 and overCITY POPULATION (THOUSANDS)_L/PUBLIC WELFARE,'EDUCATION, HOSPITALS, HEALTH, LIBRARIES, AND HOUSING AND URBAN RENEWAL._2yP0LICE AND FIRE PROTECTION, FINANCIAL ADMINISTRATION, GENERAL CONTROL, GENERAL PUBLICBUILDINGS, INTEREST ON GENERAL DEBT, AND OTHER.J7HIGHWAYS, SEWERAGE, SANITATION, PARKS AND RECREATION, AND UTILITIES.SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE.accelerate <strong>the</strong> loss <strong>of</strong> jobs. Income taxes that can be administered by acity government are apt to be crude and unprogressive payroll taxes. Andretail sales taxes administered by cities can sometimes be evaded on largepurchases.Finally, <strong>the</strong> historical boundaries <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> city government's jurisdictionhave become increasingly inadequate for planning, financing and executingefficient programs and policies in water supply, air and water pollutionabatement, transportation, and many o<strong>the</strong>r fields.In short, too many cities realize <strong>the</strong> worst <strong>of</strong> all possible worlds, withstrained budgets, inadequate expenditures for public services ranging fromeducation to law enforcement, burdensome property taxes which spur <strong>the</strong>exodus <strong>of</strong> wealthier taxpayers and discourage job-creating business, andpartial, excessively costly solutions to problems that extend far beyond <strong>the</strong>city's jurisdiction and control.MEETING THE CITIES' PROBLEMSBoth public and private investment will be required on a large scale over<strong>the</strong> next decade to improve <strong>the</strong> quantity and quality <strong>of</strong> city housing, to240-782 0—67- -11


modernize public transportation, and to upgrade o<strong>the</strong>r services provided bycity governments to <strong>the</strong>ir residents. But money is by no means <strong>the</strong> onlyrequirement.Eliminating Racial DiscriminationThe removal <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> barriers <strong>of</strong> racial discrimination in housing and jobswill pay large returns at little cost. If <strong>the</strong> Negro could secure <strong>the</strong> kind<strong>of</strong> housing that he is willing and able to pay for in <strong>the</strong> location <strong>of</strong> his choice,and if he could compete on equal terms for employment, <strong>the</strong> ordinaryprocesses <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> market would lead to substantial improvements in <strong>the</strong>housing stock and would eliminate some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> worst manifestations <strong>of</strong>poverty. Racial discrimination imposes large costs on <strong>the</strong> city. Unemploymentis higher, income is lower, housing conditions poorer, andwelfare budgets larger than <strong>the</strong>y would be if <strong>the</strong> Negro were free to seekhis best options. To begin to unlock <strong>the</strong> resources <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> city, <strong>the</strong> resources<strong>of</strong> individuals must be unchained. The only cost entailed will be<strong>the</strong> sacrifice <strong>of</strong> prejudices.The human resources <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> city are also wasted by inadequate trainingand education and by outmoded public transportation systems. Thedemand for unskilled labor is rising very slowly, and jobs <strong>of</strong> all descriptionsare increasingly located outside <strong>the</strong> city. Training and education, as well asbetter public transportation, are <strong>the</strong>refore indispensable in bringing enoughjobs within reach <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> city's labor force.Improvements in income maintenance programs, discussed earlier in thischapter, are especially urgent in <strong>the</strong> city, where <strong>the</strong> physical concentration<strong>of</strong> poverty magnifies health, welfare, and safety hazards. The elimination<strong>of</strong> racial discrimination in jobs and housing, <strong>the</strong> alleviation <strong>of</strong> extremepoverty, and more adequate education and training for <strong>the</strong> city's populationwould, in combination, gradually cure many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> city's present ills.But some ailments require more than this.Housing and Urban RenewalHousing is a key additional requirement. It has been estimated that,for <strong>the</strong> Nation as a whole, about 2 million housing units a year will have tobe built over <strong>the</strong> next decade to meet population growth and to replaceunits too dilapidated to be worth repairing. It is clear that mosthousing will be built ei<strong>the</strong>r in cities or <strong>the</strong>ir suburbs, and that muchreplacement building will be in <strong>the</strong> central cities <strong>the</strong>mselves. Most <strong>of</strong> thisnew construction will be financed privately, as it is now. But public effortswill also be needed to assist <strong>the</strong> poor—urban and rural—to acquire <strong>the</strong>housing <strong>the</strong>y need.While <strong>the</strong> Federal Government has been assisting local highway constructionand urban renewal for many years and has helped to removemany unsightly slums, it has been slow in aiding those displaced by some158


<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> projects. After <strong>the</strong> demolition <strong>of</strong> unsatisfactory housing, <strong>the</strong> poorhave sometimes been worse <strong>of</strong>f, having to crowd into <strong>the</strong> reduced supply<strong>of</strong> cheap housing still available.Public policies for housing <strong>the</strong> city's poor have advanced throughseveral stages. Newly constructed public housing has been made availableat low cost to those with incomes below a fixed level. To assure that only<strong>the</strong> poor occupy such housing, families are required to vacate if <strong>the</strong>ir incomesrise substantially and if <strong>the</strong>re is o<strong>the</strong>r good housing <strong>the</strong>y can afford in <strong>the</strong>community. This tends to leave in public housing <strong>the</strong> chronically poorfamilies, least able to help <strong>the</strong>mselves. Moreover, local public authoritieshave had difficulty producing an adequate number <strong>of</strong> housing units throughthis approach.Rent Supplements. The newly adopted Rent Supplement program <strong>of</strong>ferspromise <strong>of</strong> increasing <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> low-income housing by tapping privateresources. Under this program, multifamily housing will be constructedand operated by approved nonpr<strong>of</strong>it or limited pr<strong>of</strong>it private sponsors.Subsidies to tenants are provided for <strong>the</strong> difference between a fair marketrental <strong>of</strong> such apartments and 25 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> assisted tenant's income.The recipient pays more <strong>of</strong> his rent as his income rises, but he is not obligedto move out.Model Cities. Public programs for renovating <strong>the</strong> cities have long takencognizance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> fact that a blighted residential area cannot effectively berestored one house at a time. But <strong>the</strong>se programs have not <strong>of</strong>ten beenapplied to <strong>the</strong> full area for which integrated advance planning is required,and have not included a full range <strong>of</strong> public services which must be coordinatedin an effective area-wide attack. The Model Cities legislation,enacted last year, was drafted in recognition <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> need for an integratedassault on urban blight. It provides for <strong>the</strong> coordinated use <strong>of</strong> alreadyexisting Federal grant and loan programs—for planning, housing, waterand sewers, health and social services, education and training, and employmentservices—and perhaps even more important, it pays for part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>cost <strong>of</strong> locally designed and administered programs in <strong>the</strong> demonstrationarea which are not covered by o<strong>the</strong>r programs. As funding increases, itwill become a major forward step in a cooperative Federal-local coordinatedeffort toward urban renovation.Community Action Programs. Solution <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> problem <strong>of</strong> poverty, likethat <strong>of</strong> urban blight, requires a coordinated attack. Especially in cities, <strong>the</strong>interaction <strong>of</strong> people and <strong>the</strong> interrelations among such problems as lowincomes, lack <strong>of</strong> education, substandard housing, and ill health mean thata piecemeal approach is inadequate. More than 1,000 Community ActionAgencies supported by <strong>the</strong> Office <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Opportunity, now providethis coordination, bringing toge<strong>the</strong>r needy clients and available services.Neighborhood centers are serving as a vehicle for decentralizing and im-159


proving <strong>the</strong> delivery <strong>of</strong> social services to disadvantaged people. The Administrationis requesting that funds be provided to increase <strong>the</strong> serviceswhich can be made available in rural areas as well as in cities.Cost Reduction. Opportunities to reduce <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> housing improvementsmust be sought and pursued. The high cost <strong>of</strong> construction laborputs a premium on <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> labor-saving devices. But institutional barriersto <strong>the</strong> introduction <strong>of</strong> new techniques must be overcome. More needs tobe done in research and experimentation leading to <strong>the</strong> development andperfection <strong>of</strong> new techniques. And new ways must be sought to use publicfunds to harness private initiative and private resources.Pricing PoliciesFinally, <strong>the</strong> potential efficiency <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> market should be recognized in allareas <strong>of</strong> city life. Transportation is a notable case where <strong>the</strong> logic <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>price system is <strong>of</strong>ten violated. Bridge and tunnel tolls typically remain <strong>the</strong>same whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> road is jammed or empty. If polluters were forced tobear <strong>the</strong> costs imposed by <strong>the</strong>ir actions, <strong>the</strong> quantity <strong>of</strong> pollution wouldbe substantially reduced. Subsidized airport landing fees may encourageexcessive private use <strong>of</strong> crowded facilities. The pricing <strong>of</strong> public transportation<strong>of</strong>ten fails to take into account <strong>the</strong> external benefits arising fromdecongestion <strong>of</strong> highways. Similiarly, more rational pricing systems forwater and sewer service in many <strong>of</strong> our cities could both increase efficiencyin <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> existing capacities and reduce <strong>the</strong> planning and financialburdens <strong>of</strong> city governments.SummaryThe fundamental challenge to <strong>the</strong> city is to achieve an orderly transitionto a new pattern <strong>of</strong> land use which reflects <strong>the</strong> new requirements <strong>of</strong> industryand people. All <strong>of</strong> its policies (zoning, taxation, transportation)and all <strong>of</strong> its investments (in housing, public buildings, and education)must be geared to encourage <strong>the</strong> emergence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> new patterns. This isessentially what is meant by comprehensive planning, and it is <strong>the</strong> kind <strong>of</strong>objective which is sought in <strong>the</strong> Model Cities program and planned metropolitandevelopment incentive grants. The recently established NationalCommission on Codes, Zoning, Taxation and Development Standards willexplore ways by which cities can undertake creative change.The cost <strong>of</strong> dealing with <strong>the</strong> overwhelming problems <strong>of</strong> poverty, housing,physical and human renewal exceeds <strong>the</strong> revenue potential <strong>of</strong> many cities.If each city were required to achieve a financial balance within its ownborders, it would be forced to neglect some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> most pressing social problems<strong>of</strong> our time. There is no escape from <strong>the</strong> conclusion that <strong>the</strong> FederalGovernment must continue to provide a share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> resources cities need toremain engines <strong>of</strong> economic and social progress.160


FEDERAL, STATE, AND LOCAL FISCAL RELATIONSSince World War II, State and local expenditures have been growing farmore rapidly than Federal outlays. To finance <strong>the</strong>ir budgets, <strong>the</strong>se governmentshave increased tax rates and assessments frequently; yet State andlocal debt has increased sevenfold. Over <strong>the</strong> same period, Federal receiptshave generally kept pace with expenditures in peacetime, despite reductionsin tax rates; and <strong>the</strong> net Federal debt has risen only one-fifth, falling sharplyin relation to GNP.The problem <strong>of</strong> matching revenues with expenditure responsibilitiesis a never-ending one in our Federal system. Partly by historical accident,<strong>the</strong> Federal Government has developed <strong>the</strong> best source <strong>of</strong> revenue, namely<strong>the</strong> income tax. But increasing urbanization and o<strong>the</strong>r factors have swelled<strong>the</strong> demand for public services which are regarded as primarily <strong>the</strong> responsibility<strong>of</strong> State and local governments—both by tradition and by <strong>the</strong> preference<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> American people for keeping government as close to home aspossible.TAXATIONThe Federal Government obtains two-thirds <strong>of</strong> its revenues from taxes onpersonal and business incomes. Despite its imperfections, <strong>the</strong> Federalindividual income tax is one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> best taxes ever devised. By taxing largerincomes at higher rates, it squares with <strong>the</strong> American notion <strong>of</strong> equity. Itsrevenue yield rises strongly as <strong>the</strong> economy grows. It serves as a built-instabilizer by varying with economic fluctuations. By comparison witho<strong>the</strong>r taxes, it interferes least with job choices and expenditure decisions.The States rely principally on sales and excise taxes, and local governmentson property taxes. Broad-based personal income taxes, now leviedby 33 States, were enacted in most cases before <strong>the</strong> Federal Governmentbegan to draw heavily on this source in World War II. A small number <strong>of</strong>cities use "income" taxes—usually in <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> payroll levies. Tables26 and 27 show <strong>the</strong> relative importance <strong>of</strong> different sources <strong>of</strong> revenueand <strong>of</strong> expenditure requirements in 1965.Sales and property taxes are regressive. A poor family pays a substantialsales tax in most States even if it owes nothing under <strong>the</strong> Federal incometax. Sales taxes also discriminate among taxpayers in similar economiccircumstances. Families with <strong>the</strong> same incomes but different patterns <strong>of</strong>consumption may pay different amounts; and large families may bear arelatively heavier burden than small families. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> yield <strong>of</strong>sales taxes is less responsive than that <strong>of</strong> income taxes to economic growth.Property taxes, which are <strong>the</strong> major source <strong>of</strong> financing for education, areespecially objectionable to homeowners who have no children and causehardships for those who own <strong>the</strong>ir own homes but have relatively low currentincomes. They can also discourage private efforts to rehabilitate andupgrade declining neighborhoods. Because so much trade and commerce161


TABLE 26.—Federal and State and local government receipts, by source, nationalincome and product accounts, 1965SourceAmount (billions <strong>of</strong>dollars)FederalGovernmentState andlocal governmentsPercentage distributioniFederalGovernmentState andlocal governmentsTotal receipts.124.975.3100.0100.0Individual income taxes 2 ._-_Licenses, fees, and o<strong>the</strong>r taxes and charges on personsCorporate pr<strong>of</strong>its tax accrualsSales and excise taxes and customs 2Real estate and business property taxesO<strong>the</strong>r business taxes, fees, and chargesContributions for social insurance___Federal grants-in-aid51.32.929.115.81.124.84.47.42.015.923.16.94.511.241.12.323.312.619.85.92.721.130.79.15.914.91 Based on receipts in millions <strong>of</strong> dollars.2 Less tax refunds.NOTE.—Detail will not necessarily add to totals because <strong>of</strong> rounding.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce.is interstate, attempts by States to tax sales and income <strong>of</strong>ten make administrationcomplex and costly and create problems in taxpayer complianceand frictions among States in apportioning revenue sources.STATE AND LOCAL FISCAL PROBLEMThe States and localities have not been idle in <strong>the</strong> face <strong>of</strong> mounting demandsfor public services. Since 1959, for example, <strong>the</strong> 50 States haveTABLE 27.—Federal and State and local government expenditures, by major function,national income and product accounts, 1965Amount (billions <strong>of</strong> dollars)Percentage distribution 'Total expenditures-FunctionDefense, space, veterans, and internationalEducationHealth, hospitals, and sanitationSocial security, welfare, and laborPolice, fire, and correctionHighwaysPostal services, public utilities, commerce,and nonhighway transportationHousing, community development,and recreationAgriculture and natural resourcesInterest and general governmentFederal GovernmentTotal excludinggran tsin-aid112.266.0.51.223.1.12.6.35.912.3Grantsin-aidtoState andlocal govrnments11.2.4.7.74.53.8Stateandlocalgovernments1 Based on expenditures in millions <strong>of</strong> dollars.2 Less than $50 million.NOTE.—Detail will not necessarily add to totals because <strong>of</strong> rounding.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce.l6273.7.428.97.67.15.111.31.61.61.58.8Federal Government100.058.9.51.120.6.1.12.3.25.311.0Stateandlocalgovernments100.04.0 .06.6 39.26.3 10.340.3 9.66.934.2 15.32.14.6 2.13.1 2.0.4 11.9Total excludinggrantsin-aidGrantsin-aidtoState andlocal governments


enacted about 200 increases in <strong>the</strong> rates <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir major taxes, and imposed15 new taxes, including 8 new retail sales taxes.In <strong>the</strong> years ahead, <strong>the</strong> financial pressures on States and localities in <strong>the</strong>aggregate may moderate somewhat. The age category that produces <strong>the</strong>.largest per capita need for public services—school-age children—will growless rapidly than <strong>the</strong> working age population. Never<strong>the</strong>less, pressures willstill be strong, especially to meet <strong>the</strong> massive problems <strong>of</strong> cities imposedby decades <strong>of</strong> neglect. According to detailed estimates recently made for<strong>the</strong> Joint <strong>Economic</strong> Committee, construction needs <strong>of</strong> State and local governmentsin <strong>the</strong> next decade will equal those <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> last decade.Thus <strong>the</strong> financial problems <strong>of</strong> State and local governments will persist.Currently, increased defense expenditures dominate <strong>the</strong> Federal budget picture.But over <strong>the</strong> long run, <strong>the</strong>re is every prospect <strong>of</strong> a return to <strong>the</strong> fiscalparadox <strong>of</strong> recent years—booming income tax revenues for <strong>the</strong> FederalGovernment while States and localities struggle to finance <strong>the</strong>ir massiveprogram requirements.CATEGORICAL FEDERAL AIDThe Federal Government now provides many grants-in-aid in support<strong>of</strong> specific categories <strong>of</strong> State and local expenditure. Federal grants nowconstitute about one-sixth <strong>of</strong> total revenues <strong>of</strong> State and local governments.The first large Federal grant programs were for emergency reliefand public assistance during <strong>the</strong> 1930 J s. Federal grants declined duringWorld War II, but <strong>the</strong>n grew rapidly in <strong>the</strong> 1950's, with highway constructiongrants producing an acceleration in <strong>the</strong> second half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> decade(Table 28).TABLE28.- -Growth <strong>of</strong> Federal aid to State and local governments, fiscal years1930-68 xFunction 1930 1940 1950 1955 1960 1965 19G8 3Billions <strong>of</strong> dollarsTotal Federal aid.Health, labor, and welfareCommerce and transportationEducation__Housing and community development...Agriculture and agricultural resourcesNatural resourcesO<strong>the</strong>r( 3 )0.12.42.2.2( 3 )( 3 )( 3 )( 3 )( 3 )2.31.6.5( 3 )( 3 )( 3 )'( 3 )3.31.9.6.2.12.1.17.02.93.0.4.3.2.2.110.94.44.4.6.6.5.3.117.48.04.32.51.3.6.5.2PercentFederal aid as percent <strong>of</strong>:Federal expenditures 4State and local expenditures 4 4.31.425.625.35.310.54.810.47.714.79.215.410.318.71 Grants-in-aid and shared revenues from both administrative budget and trust funds.2 Data for 1968 are estimates.3 Less than $50 million.4 National income and product accounts basis.NOTE.—Detail will not necessarily add to totals because <strong>of</strong> rounding.Source: Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Budget.163


The last few years have seen a rapid acceleration <strong>of</strong> Federal aid througha variety <strong>of</strong> new or expanded programs—most notably for elementary andsecondary education and to combat poverty. In fact, most new legislationin areas discussed in this chapter operates through grants or loans to Stateand local governments.The grant-in-aid approach is flexible. It enables <strong>the</strong> Federal Governmentto single out <strong>the</strong> most urgent needs and to apply suitable remedies directly.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, by imposing matching formulas where appropriate, <strong>the</strong> FederalGovernment <strong>of</strong>ten can enlist additional State effort in neglected areas.Variable matching requirements are used by <strong>the</strong> Federal Government to payfor a greater share <strong>of</strong> costs in States and areas where needs are greatest relativeto available resources. Federal grants can encourage innovation at <strong>the</strong> locallevel, and provide for experimentation and demonstration where <strong>the</strong> problemsare more obvious than <strong>the</strong> remedies. They can be launched modestlyand expanded upon demonstration <strong>of</strong> effectiveness. The grant approachcan spur better planning and coordination among overlapping or adjacent—and sometimes conflicting—local jurisdictions where a regional or areawideproblem requires a cooperative and coordinated attack.At <strong>the</strong> same time, <strong>the</strong> categorical grant mechanism is open to somecriticisms. State and local <strong>of</strong>ficials are sometimes bewildered by <strong>the</strong> number,variety, and complexity <strong>of</strong> eligibility and matching provisions <strong>of</strong> differentFederal aid programs. A special effort is necessary to keep <strong>the</strong>m informed<strong>of</strong> latest developments, so that all eligible units <strong>of</strong> government may shareequitably. And some localities resent Federal standards and "supervision"in grant programs.Broadening <strong>the</strong> Scope <strong>of</strong> Federal GrantsSupporters <strong>of</strong> categorical aid argue that, while <strong>the</strong>re may be faults in <strong>the</strong>present system, <strong>the</strong>y are not intrinsic. Many steps have already been takento improve grant programs. The Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Budget has undertakenrecently to improve <strong>the</strong> coordination <strong>of</strong> Federal programs at <strong>the</strong> State andlocal level. The Partnership in Health act <strong>of</strong> last year combined severalsmall, categorical grant authorizations into one and provided assistance forplanning comprehensive health services. Similarly, <strong>the</strong> Model Cities programprovides for <strong>the</strong> coordinated use <strong>of</strong> funds from a number <strong>of</strong> separatecategorical programs as well as from private and local government sources; italso authorizes Federal assistance for local government programs in <strong>the</strong>demonstration area <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> city even if <strong>the</strong>se would not qualify for any categoricalaid. The Community Action Program <strong>of</strong>fers cities support for abroad range <strong>of</strong> activities that fit into a coordinated attack on poverty.These new programs <strong>of</strong> broad support represent a major evolution frommany traditional types <strong>of</strong> categorical grants in which <strong>the</strong> Federal Governmentpinpoints <strong>the</strong> State and local expenditures it will support.These developments are viewed by some observers as a decisive argumentfor an evolutionary approach that continues to rely on categorical aid as <strong>the</strong>164


principle vehicle by which Federal assistance should be given to State andlocal governments. These observers would argue that effectiveness is limitedonly by <strong>the</strong> amounts that <strong>the</strong> Federal Government can afford to channel toStates and localities, ra<strong>the</strong>r than by any inherent defects in <strong>the</strong> mechanism<strong>of</strong> categorical aid.GENERAL SUPPORT GRANTSO<strong>the</strong>rs contend, however, that broader "general support" grants areneeded as part <strong>of</strong> Federal support to States and localities. In principle,<strong>the</strong>se grants would have no strings attached, and would be available for generalbudget support ra<strong>the</strong>r than tied to specific activities or programs. Directtransfers without supervision would leave <strong>the</strong> States and cities free to setpriorities and to design remedies for local problems. The unconditionalgrant approach lends itself readily to "equalization," to take account <strong>of</strong>differences in income levels and fiscal capacity among <strong>the</strong> States. Manyproposals recommend setting <strong>the</strong> size <strong>of</strong> such grants as a percentage <strong>of</strong> collectionsunder <strong>the</strong> Federal individual income tax. One would earmark 5percent <strong>of</strong> collections from <strong>the</strong> Federal individual income tax for generalsupport grants to <strong>the</strong> States.Critics <strong>of</strong> general support grants have questioned whe<strong>the</strong>r State governmentswould spend <strong>the</strong> added revenues wisely, whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y would maintain<strong>the</strong>ir own revenue efforts, and whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y would provide adequately for<strong>the</strong>ir own cities. Unconditional grants to <strong>the</strong> States are viewed by some as athreat to additional Congressional appropriations for categorical grant programswhich provide direct assistance to cities and <strong>the</strong>ir pressing problems.Also, if States had a claim on a share <strong>of</strong> Federal revenues, <strong>the</strong>y might opposeFederal tax reduction even when needed to combat recession. And if <strong>the</strong>cut were never<strong>the</strong>less approved, its effectiveness could be weakened by aresulting cutback in State outlays.Supporters <strong>of</strong> revenue-sharing point out that formulas can be devised tocope with cyclical swings in general support grants and to channel funds tolocalities as well as States. However, <strong>the</strong>re are obvious difficulties.Under some proposed compromise arrangements, a fixed level would beestablished for total Federal financial aid to State and local government,designed to cover both categorical grants and general support. Categoricalgrants would continue to be appropriated as at present; and <strong>the</strong> balance <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> support would take <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> untied grants going to cities as well asStates. The untied portion would serve as an "overhead" payment to beused by States and cities to streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>ir own programs and <strong>the</strong>ir planning.Such a compromise is intended to provide some assurance <strong>of</strong> continuedFederal support for categorical grant programs which have established <strong>the</strong>irmerit, while enlarging opportunities for State and local initiative andresponsibility.165


CREDIT FOR STATE INCOME TAXESAn additional method <strong>of</strong> enlarging State revenues in <strong>the</strong> context <strong>of</strong> animproved over-all national tax structure has been proposed by <strong>the</strong> AdvisoryCommission on Intergovernment Relations. The suggestion is that a creditagainst Federal personal income tax liability be given for up to 40 percent <strong>of</strong>State income taxes paid. This credit would provide powerful incentives:<strong>the</strong> 17 States which do not now have broad-based individual incometaxes would be strongly induced to enact <strong>the</strong>m; States which already haveincome taxes would be encouraged to rely on <strong>the</strong>m more heavily. A Statecould <strong>the</strong>n augment its revenues through income taxation with a net increasein <strong>the</strong> burden on State taxpayers equal to only 60 percent <strong>of</strong> addedrevenue. Through <strong>the</strong> credit device, <strong>the</strong> States would, in effect, be collectingpart <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir income taxes from <strong>the</strong> Federal Government.Federal tax credits to influence local tax policy are not new. They areapplied to estate or inheritance taxes paid to States, and <strong>the</strong>y are used under<strong>the</strong> Federal-State unemployment insurance system.The tax credit device has been subjected to certain criticisms. First,by <strong>the</strong>ir very nature, tax credits provide more help to rich States than to poorStates, because <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> assistance depends on <strong>the</strong> tax base <strong>of</strong> eachState. Second, <strong>the</strong> proposal does not in itself provide direct aid to <strong>the</strong> cities.Third, <strong>the</strong> Federal tax credit adds to State revenues only when and if <strong>the</strong>States act to initiate or raise rates on income taxes; <strong>the</strong> initial impact merelylowers Federal taxes for people who now pay State income taxes.JOINT REVENUE COLLECTIONIt has also been proposed that <strong>the</strong> Internal Revenue Service (IRS) expandits current assistance to <strong>the</strong> States in <strong>the</strong>ir income tax collection efforts. Atpresent, <strong>the</strong>re is cooperative exchange <strong>of</strong> information between Federal andState revenue <strong>of</strong>ficials. But <strong>the</strong> IRS could act as collecting agent for Stateincome taxes. The State rate structure would be applied against <strong>the</strong> Federaldefinition <strong>of</strong> taxable or adjusted gross income or Federal tax liability itself.Joint revenue collection is a modest proposal which could be enacted on itsown merits or as a supplement to <strong>the</strong> larger plans. It might encourage additionalStates to enact income taxes, and should certainly simplify life for bothtaxpayers and revenue <strong>of</strong>ficials in States which already use income taxes.It would, <strong>of</strong> course, be necessary for <strong>the</strong> States to follow Federal concepts <strong>of</strong>taxable income, which may not always accord with <strong>the</strong>ir own.OTHER ISSUES OF TAX COORDINATIONAmong o<strong>the</strong>r problems requiring better coordination <strong>of</strong> Federal-Statelocaltaxation is one dealing with <strong>the</strong> exemption from taxation, under <strong>the</strong>Federal individual income tax, <strong>of</strong> interest paid on State and local governmentsecurities. Because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> exemption, <strong>the</strong>se governments can borrowmore cheaply—paying lower rates <strong>of</strong> interest and competing more effectively166


for funds against o<strong>the</strong>r borrowers in capital markets. However, <strong>the</strong> exemptionalso reduces <strong>the</strong> progressivity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal individual income tax,since it produces much bigger tax savings to those in high income taxbrackets than to those taxable at lower rates. This is a relatively inefficientmeans <strong>of</strong> channeling aid: <strong>the</strong> Federal Government loses far more revenuethan <strong>the</strong> States and cities gain in reduced interest costs.Apart from <strong>the</strong> general question <strong>of</strong> interest exemption, and <strong>of</strong> immediateconcern, is <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> so-called industrial development bonds. Through<strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se bonds, localities have passed to private industries <strong>the</strong> benefit<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> exemption <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir interest from Federal tax, in many cases withoutassuming any real obligation for repayment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> bonds. This questionablepractice is becoming increasingly widespread, and <strong>the</strong> lack <strong>of</strong> any obligationby <strong>the</strong> locality authorizing <strong>the</strong> bonds permits proliferation without limit.The use <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal tax code in this fashion is inefficient and inappropriate.Ano<strong>the</strong>r fiscal problem concerns State taxation <strong>of</strong> corporate income.Since most corporate income is generated by interstate corporations, Statesmust establish formulas to apportion <strong>the</strong> income assumed to be earned frombusiness done in o<strong>the</strong>r areas. The formulas give various weights to suchfactors as location <strong>of</strong> plant, percent <strong>of</strong> payroll, sales destination, location <strong>of</strong>sales <strong>of</strong>fices, and "origin" <strong>of</strong> sales. In 1966, after several years <strong>of</strong> study, <strong>the</strong>House Judiciary Committee recommended legislation that would require auniform State formula based solely on two factors, property and payroll.The States have responded unfavorably to this proposal. As an alternative,additional Federal grants to <strong>the</strong> States might be used to persuade <strong>the</strong>m torelinquish a tax which is more efficiently collected at <strong>the</strong> national level.CONCLUSIONExpenditures for income maintenance, health, and education, andrevenues <strong>of</strong> States and cities, have grown faster than GNP since <strong>the</strong> mid-1950's. Expenditures for educational services and health care combinedhave risen from about 8J4 percent to 12^2 percent <strong>of</strong> GNP, and expenditures<strong>of</strong> States and localities have expanded from 8J/2 percent to 11 percent<strong>of</strong> national output in <strong>the</strong> past decade. Federal transfer payments to personshave risen from 3 percent to 4^2 percent <strong>of</strong> GNP. Through <strong>the</strong>ir dollarvotes on <strong>the</strong> market and <strong>the</strong>ir votes at <strong>the</strong> polls^ Americans have reaffirmed<strong>the</strong>ir strong desires for greater expenditures in <strong>the</strong>se areas.In response to <strong>the</strong> wishes <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> public, <strong>the</strong>se areas will continue to absorba significant fraction <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> gains from economic growth. But it is impossiblereliably to forecast how rapidly <strong>the</strong>se outlays will grow, or to set inadvance meaningful targets for how fast <strong>the</strong>y should increase. Opportunitiesfor progress in <strong>the</strong>se areas will be influenced by <strong>the</strong> urgency <strong>of</strong> competingclaims on output, ranging from national defense to <strong>the</strong> unlimited aspira-167


tions <strong>of</strong> private consumers, and from conservation <strong>of</strong> natural resources andimprovements in <strong>the</strong> quality <strong>of</strong> our environment to industrial research, development,and investment. In peacetime <strong>the</strong> Nation will face repeated anddifficult—though welcome—choices about how to distribute fiscal dividendsbetween public programs and tax reductions. These decisions should beresponsive to changing circumstances.Moreover, it is not possible to stipulate "needs" in <strong>the</strong> areas discussed inthis chapter. If needs are merely what survival requires, most <strong>of</strong> what isneeded is now available. And if needs are everything that could be reasonablydesired, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>y will not be fully met for generations.A rational balancing <strong>of</strong> opportunities and alternatives, will undoubtedlycall for some progress in all <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se—and o<strong>the</strong>r—priority areas. Most<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> choices, both public and private, will be incremental in character.The individual chooses whe<strong>the</strong>r or not to visit his dentist, weighing <strong>the</strong> needagainst o<strong>the</strong>r uses <strong>of</strong> funds; he does not decide on health in <strong>the</strong> abstractor in <strong>the</strong> large. Similarly, <strong>the</strong> Federal budgetary process is full <strong>of</strong> effortsto cut low-priority expenditures marginally in order to expedite a promisingnew program like model cities. Even major program decisions which willbe faced in <strong>the</strong> years ahead—such as whe<strong>the</strong>r or not to set a minimum incomefloor to combat poverty, or whe<strong>the</strong>r or not to select any <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> proposedinnovations in <strong>the</strong> area <strong>of</strong> Federal-State-local fiscal relations—could also beapproached on an incremental basis. In making <strong>the</strong>se budgetary decisions, itis vitally important that goals and objectives be defined precisely, that allalternative methods <strong>of</strong> reaching <strong>the</strong>m be considered, that costs and benefitsbe quantified as far as possible; only <strong>the</strong>n can <strong>the</strong> most efficient means <strong>of</strong>achieving <strong>the</strong> objectives be chosen. The Planning-Programming-BudgetingSystem recently initiated by <strong>the</strong> Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Budget and <strong>the</strong>executive agencies <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Government is designed to advance thissystematic approach.This chapter has attempted to raise some issues which will require difficultchoices. Collectively such decisions will determine <strong>the</strong> directions <strong>of</strong> socialprogress in <strong>the</strong> years ahead.It is clear that social progress will make important claims on <strong>the</strong> Federalbudget. There is no easy way to define <strong>the</strong> Government's appropriaterole. But <strong>the</strong> pursuit <strong>of</strong> public interest and <strong>the</strong> exercise <strong>of</strong> public responsibilityneed not add dollar-for-dollar to <strong>the</strong> bills <strong>of</strong> taxpayers or to <strong>the</strong> size<strong>of</strong> Government. Much <strong>of</strong> our advance in health, education, and cities willbe financed through <strong>the</strong> budgets <strong>of</strong> consumers and businesses. The energiesand outlays <strong>of</strong> private enterprise can be stimulated by wise and imaginativepublic policies relying on enlightened regulation, carefully designed feesand subsidies, appropriate tax provisions, Government loans and insuranceprograms, and improved functioning <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> market economy so that actualprices become better signals for estimating social costs and benefits.Within <strong>the</strong> public sector, ano<strong>the</strong>r set <strong>of</strong> issues arises: whe<strong>the</strong>r particularprograms can be administered and financed most effectively by Federal,168


State, or local governments, and how <strong>the</strong> over-all division <strong>of</strong> responsibilitiescan assure adequate financing for priority social needs through anequitable tax system.The aspirations for material and social progress are boundless; <strong>the</strong> limits<strong>of</strong> our potential progress are set by <strong>the</strong> resource costs and <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> productivityin our society. It can be confidently forecast that <strong>the</strong> problemwill be to find <strong>the</strong> means to fulfill our public and private aspirations ra<strong>the</strong>rthan to deal with any redundancy <strong>of</strong> resources. A decade from now, majorgains will have been made, but <strong>the</strong>re will still be a large inventory <strong>of</strong> unmetdesires and unsolved social problems, requiring public and private effortsto channel a substantial additional portion <strong>of</strong> our growing output towardpriority uses.169


Chapter 5Growth and Balance in <strong>the</strong> World EconomyWORLD ECONOMIC EXPANSION in <strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1960's hasbeen sustained and rapid. The pace has probably been surpassedonly during <strong>the</strong> period <strong>of</strong> recovery from World War II. Moreover, since<strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> war, <strong>the</strong> extreme fluctuations <strong>of</strong> earlier years have not beenrepeated.But continued economic progress is not assured. Many problems remain.The most difficult and important is that <strong>of</strong> overcoming poverty in many<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> less developed countries <strong>of</strong> Africa, Asia, and Latin America. A majorproblem for <strong>the</strong> developed countries is to cope with international financialimbalances in ways which do not inhibit sound economic growth.This chapter records <strong>the</strong> economic progress in both <strong>the</strong> developed andless developed countries during <strong>the</strong> first part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1960's and outlines somemajor issues for international consideration during <strong>the</strong> remainder <strong>of</strong> thisdecade. It deals especially with <strong>the</strong> policy issues facing <strong>the</strong> United Statesand o<strong>the</strong>r developed countries in <strong>the</strong>ir efforts to achieve a better internationalbalance and to pursue national policies that promote world economicprogress. The worldwide economic impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir national policies placesa special responsibility on <strong>the</strong> major developed countries.WORLD ECONOMIC GROWTH IN THE 1960'STwo quantitative goals for economic growth in <strong>the</strong> 1960's have beenfixed by international organizations:The United Nations has set 5 percent a year as <strong>the</strong> minimumgrowth rate for <strong>the</strong> less developed countries over <strong>the</strong> 1960's, callingthis <strong>the</strong> "Development Decade."The Organization for <strong>Economic</strong> Cooperation and Development(OECD), which includes <strong>the</strong> countries <strong>of</strong> Western Europe, <strong>the</strong> UnitedStates, Canada, and Japan, has called for an increase in aggregateoutput <strong>of</strong> all member countries combined, amounting to 50 percentover <strong>the</strong> decade or an average annual growth rate <strong>of</strong> 4.1 percent.As can be seen from Table 29, <strong>the</strong> expansion <strong>of</strong> real output in <strong>the</strong> lessdeveloped countries, estimated at 4/ 2 percent a year, so far has fallensomewhat short <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> UN target on average, and far below it in several170


TABLE 29.—Changes in total and per capita real GNP in OECD and less developedcountries since 1955CountryShare <strong>of</strong>totaloutput(percent) 1Percentage increase per yearTotal real GNP1955to19601960to1965Per capita realGNP1955to19601960to1965OECD countries: Total100.03.25.02.03.7United States53.32.24.7.43.2Total excluding United States.46.75.05.33.74.2GermanyUnited Kingdom.FranceJapanItaly -SpainGreece. . .Less developed countries: TotalAfricaNigeria.Ghana.. .8.67.77.35.44.11.4.4100.012.51.3 .72 6.32.84.69.75.54.35.4*4.5(5)( 5 ) 6.13 4.83.35.19.75.19.28.74.63.3 5.04.02 5.12.23.78.84.93.44.3


Japan to less than 14 percent in <strong>the</strong> United Kingdom. While much <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>increase in output comes from investment in physical capital and from <strong>the</strong>incorporation <strong>of</strong> technological advances, a good deal also comes from investmentin human capital—in raising <strong>the</strong> education, skills, and health <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>population.The growth <strong>of</strong> output is also benefiting from <strong>the</strong> movement <strong>of</strong> labor out <strong>of</strong>activities <strong>of</strong> low productivity to those <strong>of</strong> higher productivity. There has beena large-scale movement <strong>of</strong> labor from Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Europe to NorthwesternEurope—from areas <strong>of</strong> low productivity, low incomes, and high unemploymentto areas where productivity and incomes are high and unemploymentlow. Within countries, <strong>the</strong> major shift has been out <strong>of</strong> employment in agriculture.The OEGD estimates that this latter shift alone accounted forbetween 10 and 15 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> increase in productivity during <strong>the</strong> firsthalf <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1960's in France, Germany, Italy, and Japan. The United Kingdom,which by 1960 already had only a small agricultural sector, did nothave this source <strong>of</strong> expanding productivity.Internal shifts <strong>of</strong> labor have been stimulated and facilitated by <strong>the</strong>expansion <strong>of</strong> foreign trade, which has far exceeded <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> output.The rapid growth <strong>of</strong> trade has resulted, in part, from <strong>the</strong> reduction <strong>of</strong> tradebarriers, especially within <strong>the</strong> two regional groupings—<strong>the</strong> European <strong>Economic</strong>Community (EEC) and <strong>the</strong> European Free Trade Association(EFTA).For a number <strong>of</strong> European countries and Japan, a rapid rise in exportshas also directly stimulated <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> GNP. In addition, whendomestic expansion is led by export growth, <strong>the</strong> resulting rise in importscan be readily financed; <strong>the</strong>re is less chance that <strong>the</strong> government will needto apply <strong>the</strong> brakes to reverse a developing balance <strong>of</strong> payments deficit.LESS DEVELOPED COUNTRIESThe achievement <strong>of</strong> an adequate rate <strong>of</strong> self-sustaining growth in <strong>the</strong>less developed countries remains an urgent world economic problem. Overhalf <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 4J/2 percent annual growth <strong>of</strong> total output for <strong>the</strong> less developedareas has been needed just to maintain <strong>the</strong>ir low level <strong>of</strong> living, since <strong>the</strong>irpopulations have been rising by 2^2 percent annually. The yearly increasein per capita output has been only 2 percent, or barely $3 a person.Achieving rapid and sustainable growth in <strong>the</strong>se countries is by no meansa hopeless task, however. Self-sustaining growth has been attained in certainless developed countries—including Israel, Malaysia, Mexico, Taiwan,Venezuela, and some Central American countries. O<strong>the</strong>rs—such as Pakistan,South Korea, Thailand, and Turkey—are approaching that objective.But <strong>the</strong> problems are formidable. Fur<strong>the</strong>r efforts by both <strong>the</strong> developedand <strong>the</strong> less developed countries are required. The rapid growth<strong>of</strong> population in many less developed countries, already over-populated inrelation to <strong>the</strong>ir economic resources, must be slowed. A number <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se172


nations have adopted measures to induce <strong>the</strong>ir citizens to limit <strong>the</strong> size <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong>ir families. Some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se programs—in Hong Kong, Singapore, andTaiwan—have already shown signs <strong>of</strong> success. Never<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong> growthrate <strong>of</strong> population in <strong>the</strong> less developed countries as a group is still rising.Ano<strong>the</strong>r major problem area is agriculture. Agricultural output hasgrown so slowly that food output per person in many countries is belowpre-World War II levels. Unless a vigorous effort is made to redress <strong>the</strong>situation, it is likely to deteriorate fur<strong>the</strong>r as population and need for foodcontinue to grow rapidly. Moreover, in at least some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> less developedcountries, agricultural development may be a key to general economicgrowth. The application <strong>of</strong> improved farming techniques can substantiallyimprove agricultural productivity with relatively small increments <strong>of</strong> capital;increased agricultural output can be a major substitute for imports; risingfarm income can provide an expanding market for domestic industrialoutput.The developed countries can do much to help by providing technicalassistance, food, fertilizers, agricultural equipment, and financing. But <strong>the</strong>basic responsibility rests on <strong>the</strong> less developed countries <strong>the</strong>mselves. Theymust, among o<strong>the</strong>r things, improve <strong>the</strong> incentives for farmers to increaseoutput.Education also is a major field in which improvement is essential. <strong>Economic</strong>progress requires literacy. A modern and expanding economy needsmuch more—people trained to operate farm machinery, run a la<strong>the</strong>, operatea retail store, and keep accounts. In recognition <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong>education, <strong>the</strong> less developed countries have in recent years increased <strong>the</strong>ireducation budgets by 15 percent annually. This effort has long been supportedby <strong>the</strong> United States. More Agency for International Development(AID) technicians working abroad are employed in educational projectsthan in any o<strong>the</strong>r field. Moreover, beginning in fiscal year 1967, AIDis sharply increasing its educational aid effort, as well as its work inagriculture and health. The educational efforts <strong>of</strong> our Peace Corpsworkers are also welcomed throughout <strong>the</strong> less developed world.The Need for CapitalThe developing countries also need capital. About one-fourth <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>irdomestic investment is financed by capital imports. From 1961 to 1965,<strong>the</strong> net amount <strong>of</strong> this capital inflow rose by only 5 percent a year in moneyterms and less in real terms. Some increase continued into 1966. Since1963, <strong>the</strong> entire increase from abroad has been in private capital flows.This investment, to be sure, benefits <strong>the</strong> recipient countries, and <strong>the</strong>United States has taken steps to encourage it. But it has gone mainly to<strong>the</strong> extractive industries, particularly oil. Thus, it is unevenly distributedamong countries. Fur<strong>the</strong>r, investment in technologically advanced, some-240-782 O—67 12 ' u


times highly automated, extractive processes does not have <strong>the</strong> same stimulatingeffects on general economic activity as does investment in local manufacturing.It does, however, provide much needed foreign exchange andtechnological know-how for those countries fortunate enough to be wellendowedwith minerals.For many developing nations, a growing burden <strong>of</strong> interest and amortizationpayments on external debt absorbs a large and rising proportion <strong>of</strong>gross aid receipts. In 1960, debt service charges amounted to 13 percent <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial bilateral aid receipts <strong>of</strong> less developed countries; today <strong>the</strong> figureis 19 percent. India's debt service charges on government assistance for <strong>the</strong>period <strong>of</strong> its Third Plan amounted to 26 percent <strong>of</strong> its foreign aid. InTurkey, debt service during 1963-66 was more than half as large as grossforeign aid.For <strong>the</strong> net inflow <strong>of</strong> aid merely to remain constant, <strong>the</strong> gross inflow mustrise to cover growing debt service. In fact, <strong>the</strong> gross flow <strong>of</strong> government aidfrom <strong>the</strong> developed countries has been rising just enough to keep net aid inflowon a plateau since 1963. Future prospects are even less encouraging.Bilateral aid commitments—pledges <strong>of</strong> actual aid disbursements to be madein <strong>the</strong> future—declined in 1965. This could foreshadow a decline in netand even in gross <strong>of</strong>ficial aid disbursements in <strong>the</strong> years to come.The stagnation in <strong>the</strong> net flow <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial capital to <strong>the</strong> less developedcountries has come at <strong>the</strong> very time that <strong>the</strong> industrial countries havereached new heights <strong>of</strong> prosperity. And it comes at a time when <strong>the</strong> pace<strong>of</strong> economic expansion achieved by <strong>the</strong> less developed countries as a groupis encouraging. They are developing <strong>the</strong> skills required for a moderneconomy. They are capable <strong>of</strong> using more capital than <strong>the</strong>y can raisedomestically or borrow abroad on commercial terms. For this and o<strong>the</strong>rreasons, foreign aid, both bilateral and multilateral, should have a highpriority claim on <strong>the</strong> resources <strong>of</strong> high-income countries.One <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> most fruitful avenues for increased aid to <strong>the</strong> less developedcountries is through <strong>the</strong> multilateral lending agencies—<strong>the</strong> World Bankfamily and <strong>the</strong> regional development banks. The United States firmlysupports <strong>the</strong>se agencies as mechanisms for mobilizing both external capitaland domestic resources <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> developing countries <strong>the</strong>mselves. Replenishment<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> resources <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> International Development Association (IDA),which lends on easy terms, ought to be high on <strong>the</strong> agenda <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> developedcountries. The IDA's resources should be substantially increased in wayswhich take into account <strong>the</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> payments situation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> contributingcountries. The recently established Asian Development Bank representsa new stage in Asian economic cooperation, in which <strong>the</strong> UnitedStates is participating with o<strong>the</strong>r non-Asian countries. For Latin America,<strong>the</strong> United States continues its strong support <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Inter-American DevelopmentBank, which serves as <strong>the</strong> financial arm <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Alliance for Progressand is helping to draw funds from inside and outside <strong>the</strong> hemisphere into174


Latin American development. The African Development Bank, which hasrecently begun operations, will perform similar functions in its area.Foreign aid and private foreign investment finance only one-fifth <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>foreign exchange expenditures <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> developing countries. The remainingfour-fifths is financed by <strong>the</strong>ir own export earnings. After near stagnationin <strong>the</strong> late 1950's, <strong>the</strong>se earnings rose by about 6 percent a year during<strong>the</strong> first half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1960's. The increase was produced by many factors, includingstreng<strong>the</strong>ned prices for many primary commodities, <strong>the</strong> growingability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> less developed countries to supply <strong>the</strong>se commodities, and <strong>the</strong>rapidly expanding markets in <strong>the</strong> United States, Western Europe, andJapan. Only with continued vigorous growth in <strong>the</strong> developed world andimproved access to its markets can <strong>the</strong> less developed countries earn <strong>the</strong>foreign exchange needed to support <strong>the</strong>ir own continuing growth.TRADE POLICIESThe less developed countries obviously have much to gain from reductionsin tariffs, quotas, and o<strong>the</strong>r barriers to trade in primary products, sincesuch products constitute 85 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir exports. Over <strong>the</strong> longer run,satisfactory growth in <strong>the</strong> export earnings <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> less developed countrieswill require relatively less reliance on sales <strong>of</strong> primary products and continuation<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> sharp expansion in exports <strong>of</strong> manufactured goods. Suchdiversification will also be important for <strong>the</strong>ir internal growth. Reductionsin tariffs and o<strong>the</strong>r trade barriers in developed countries can contributemuch to <strong>the</strong> needed growth <strong>of</strong> manufactured exports from developingcountries.In most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> less developed countries, internal markets are too smallto support efficient modern industrial plants. It is not geographic size orpopulation but effective purchasing power that determines <strong>the</strong> size <strong>of</strong> amarket. Regional cooperation can create larger markets so that <strong>the</strong> enterprises<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> developing countries can benefit from <strong>the</strong> economies <strong>of</strong> scaleand <strong>of</strong> specialization on which growth and efficiency depend.Encouraging progress toward regional integration is being made in anumber <strong>of</strong> areas. The Latin American Free Trade Association, despitehandicaps, can form <strong>the</strong> basis for a true Latin American common market.Particular progress has been made in <strong>the</strong> Central American Common Market.The United States supports outward-looking regional integration.The importance <strong>of</strong> trade expansion as a factor in economic growth inall countries argues strongly for more rapid trade liberalization. Thisproposition is effectively demonstrated by <strong>the</strong> recent experience in <strong>the</strong> newfree-trade areas <strong>of</strong> Europe, just as it was earlier demonstrated in <strong>the</strong> greatcommon market <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> United States. Thus, it is essential that successbe achieved in <strong>the</strong> current multilateral trade negotiations, by far <strong>the</strong> mostcomprehensive in history.175


Kennedy RoundThis success is important to both <strong>the</strong> developed and less developed countries.The substantial reduction in tariff barriers which <strong>the</strong> United Statesand o<strong>the</strong>r countries are seeking to achieve in <strong>the</strong> Kennedy Round negotiationsshould make an important contribution to increased world trade.Expanding world trade encourages capital and labor to move out <strong>of</strong> thoseeconomic activities which are better supplied from abroad and into thosefields which provide higher real income through greater productivity. Bypermitting countries to produce efficiently and on a large scale, freer trademakes a contribution to higher incomes everywhere. And through reduction<strong>of</strong> artificial shelters to laggard domestic industries, <strong>the</strong> lowering <strong>of</strong>barriers to imports spurs innovation and efficiency.In <strong>the</strong> Kennedy Round, <strong>the</strong> major reductions in barriers to world tradeare expected to be made by <strong>the</strong> developed countries—<strong>the</strong> United States,EEC, EFT A, and Japan. EFT A has now virtually eliminated barriers toindustrial trade among its members while <strong>the</strong> EEC will do so for bothindustrial and agricultural products by July 1968. The reduction <strong>of</strong> barriersto trade with nonmember countries would now help <strong>the</strong>se groups tocontinue <strong>the</strong>ir rapid pace <strong>of</strong> growth, and would avoid distortion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>normal pattern <strong>of</strong> European trade in particular and world trade generally.The less developed countries are not being asked to grant tariff concessionsthat would endanger <strong>the</strong>ir economic development programs.Longer-Run TasksA successful Kennedy Round will be a great achievement, and will promoterapid and healthy economic expansion throughout <strong>the</strong> world. But <strong>the</strong> KennedyRound cannot be <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> road for <strong>the</strong> liberalization <strong>of</strong> worldtrade. In <strong>the</strong> year ahead, fur<strong>the</strong>r study and international consultationshould be directed at four remaining tasks in <strong>the</strong> trade field:(1) Continuing efforts to liberalize those tariff and nontariff barrierswhich will remain after <strong>the</strong> Kennedy Round;(2) Developing a better international pattern <strong>of</strong> agricultural productionand trade to speed economic growth;(3) Achieving more stable export prices and raising <strong>the</strong> export volume <strong>of</strong>developing countries;(4) Improving economic relations between <strong>the</strong> countries <strong>of</strong> EasternEurope—including <strong>the</strong> Soviet Union—and <strong>the</strong> United States.<strong>President</strong> Johnson has emphasized <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> this last task on severaloccasions. In his recent State <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Union Message, he noted that <strong>the</strong>Export-Import Bank can now extend commercial credits to Bulgaria,Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland, as we'll as to Rumania and Yugoslavia.He called again for legislative authority to extend most-favorednation—i.e.,nondiscriminatory—tariff treatment to <strong>the</strong> countries <strong>of</strong> Eastern


Europe and <strong>the</strong> Soviet Union. Their trade with Western Europe has increasedsteadily in recent years, while U.S. trade with <strong>the</strong>se countries hasbeen stagnant, and constitutes less than 1 percent <strong>of</strong> all U.S. foreign trade.U.S. BALANCE OF PAYMENTSA country's foreign trade and payments are its main points <strong>of</strong> economiccontact with <strong>the</strong> rest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> world. The balance <strong>of</strong> payments <strong>of</strong> any nationis intimately dependent on policies and developments in <strong>the</strong> outside world.U.S. exports depend heavily on European, Canadian, and Japanese growthand <strong>the</strong> foreign exchange receipts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> less developed countries as well ason U.S. growth and price stability. The flow <strong>of</strong> capital from <strong>the</strong> UnitedStates depends on pr<strong>of</strong>it opportunities and monetary conditions abroad aswell as on those in <strong>the</strong> United States.For most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> decade following World War II, U.S. balance <strong>of</strong> paymentsdeficits provided needed international currency to support <strong>the</strong> rapid expansion<strong>of</strong> world trade and economic growth. O<strong>the</strong>r countries were eager tohold more dollars; indeed, it was commonly known as a period <strong>of</strong> "dollarshortage." Recently, however, as foreign reserves have increased, U.S.deficits have been less welcome.These deficits do not, <strong>of</strong> course, contradict <strong>the</strong> unmatched strength andproductivity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> U.S. economy; nei<strong>the</strong>r do <strong>the</strong>y mean that our competitiveposition in world markets is weak. The United States is not livingbeyond its means, increasing its net debt to foreign countries, or using up itsinternational capital. U.S. ownership <strong>of</strong> assets abroad continues to growfaster than foreign ownership <strong>of</strong> assets in <strong>the</strong> United States. U.S. assetsabroad, net <strong>of</strong> foreign assets in <strong>the</strong> United States, increased from $7 billionin 1935 to $14 billion in 1950; by 1961 <strong>the</strong>y had risen to $28 billion;and in 1965 <strong>the</strong>y were $47 billion.The deficits have, however, resulted in a steady erosion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> U.S. stock<strong>of</strong> reserve assets, which are needed to maintain a stable value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> dollarin international transactions. At <strong>the</strong> same time, <strong>the</strong>re have been steadyincreases in U.S. liabilities to foreigners that may be considered potentialclaims against our reserve assets. This combination implies a continuingdecline in liquidity; it is clearly not indefinitely sustainable if confidence in<strong>the</strong> safety and stability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> dollar is to be maintained.The U.S. balance <strong>of</strong> payments performance is now evaluated in terms <strong>of</strong>two alternative accounting definitions. Both measure an over-all U.S.deficit or surplus in terms <strong>of</strong> what is currently happening to (1) U.S. reservesand (2) certain types <strong>of</strong> claims against <strong>the</strong> United States. Both count asan increase or decrease in reserves any change in <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> U.S. holdings<strong>of</strong> monetary gold, U.S. "gold tranche" claims on <strong>the</strong> International MonetaryFund (IMF), and U.S. <strong>of</strong>ficial holdings <strong>of</strong> convertible foreign currencies.177


They differ in how <strong>the</strong>y treat changes in various outstanding claims against<strong>the</strong> United States.One measure—<strong>the</strong> "<strong>of</strong>ficial reserve transactions" balance—treats anyincrease in foreign private claims on <strong>the</strong> United States, liquid or illiquid, asan ordinary capital inflow. Only <strong>the</strong> change in claims on <strong>the</strong> United Statesheld by foreign <strong>of</strong>ficial agencies is counted, along with <strong>the</strong> change in U.S.reserves, as a measure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> U.S. deficit or surplus. Foreign <strong>of</strong>ficial monetaryagencies have <strong>the</strong> privilege <strong>of</strong> converting claims on <strong>the</strong> United Statesinto gold at <strong>the</strong> U.S. Treasury; <strong>the</strong>ir net purchases thus add to <strong>the</strong> directclaims on U.S. reserves. Moreover, <strong>the</strong>y are charged with maintainingstable exchange rates for <strong>the</strong>ir national currencies. They usually do thisby buying or selling dollars to close any gap between normal supply anddemand for dollars which might o<strong>the</strong>rwise upset <strong>the</strong> exchange rate between<strong>the</strong> dollar and <strong>the</strong>ir currency. In this sense, <strong>the</strong> net balance <strong>of</strong> such transactionsby o<strong>the</strong>r countries, toge<strong>the</strong>r with changes in our own reserves, is oneindicator <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> size <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> imbalance in U.S. payments.The alternative "liquidity" balance attempts an assessment <strong>of</strong> changes in<strong>the</strong> U.S. liquidity position. It takes account <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> fact that liquiddollar holdings <strong>of</strong> private foreigners may be readily sold to foreign centralbanks. It <strong>the</strong>refore treats only increases in foreign non-liquid claims on <strong>the</strong>United States as ordinary capital inflows. Changes in all liquid claims areincluded along with changes in U.S. reserve assets as a measure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> U.S.balance, regardless <strong>of</strong> whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> claims are acquired or sold by an <strong>of</strong>ficialagency or by a private individual, bank, or business.While <strong>the</strong>se measures <strong>of</strong> balance are important, <strong>the</strong>y must be viewed asindicators, ra<strong>the</strong>r than definitions, <strong>of</strong> equilibrium. In part, <strong>the</strong> limitationarises because any measure <strong>of</strong> balance must arbitrarily divide dollar assetsinto two distinct groups—those Which are claims against our reserves andthose which are not. Such a clear division does not exist in reality. Toa degree, any marketable dollar asset can be indirectly exercised asa claim against U.S. reserves. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> likelihood that assets willbe used as a claim against U.S. reserves depends not only on <strong>the</strong>ir marketabilityand maturity but also on <strong>the</strong> motivation and attitude <strong>of</strong> current andprospective holders. Evidence on such attitudes, including <strong>the</strong> performance<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> dollar in foreign exchange markets, helps to interpret <strong>the</strong> U.S. position.But, however that position is assessed, <strong>the</strong> U.S. balance <strong>of</strong> paymentsclearly has not been in sustainable equilibrium in recent years and must beimproved.Where a sustainable equilibrium may lie over <strong>the</strong> long run is not completelyclear. The expansion <strong>of</strong> international transactions—most <strong>of</strong> which are settledin dollars—suggests that some growth <strong>of</strong> foreign private holdings <strong>of</strong>dollars is natural and desirable and may be perfectly sustainable. Someincrease in <strong>of</strong>ficial claims on <strong>the</strong> United States may also occur over <strong>the</strong> longrun, given <strong>the</strong> preference <strong>of</strong> many countries to hold all or some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>of</strong>ficialreserves in dollars, and <strong>the</strong> fact that transactions needs <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial agencies178


will continue to expand. Regardless <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> movement <strong>of</strong> dollar holdingsabroad, however, continuing U.S. reserve losses would not be compatible withsustained equilibrium. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, any growth <strong>of</strong> ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>of</strong>ficial, or<strong>of</strong>ficial plus private liquid, holdings <strong>of</strong> dollars need not be precisely equaledby growth <strong>of</strong> U.S. reserve assets in order that sustainable equilibrium beachieved.REGENT DEVELOPMENTSThe U.S. liquidity deficit widened slightly in 1966 while <strong>the</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficialsettlements balance registered a small surplus for <strong>the</strong> first time since 1957,The liquidity deficit had improved markedly in 1965 and showed a slightfur<strong>the</strong>r improvement through <strong>the</strong> first three quarters <strong>of</strong> 1966. Preliminaryevidence points to a somewhat larger fourth quarter liquidity deficit whichwill bring <strong>the</strong> year's total slightly above <strong>the</strong> $1.3 billion deficit <strong>of</strong> 1965.During <strong>the</strong> year, <strong>the</strong>re was an extraordinary buildup <strong>of</strong> foreign privatedollar holdings, which resulted in a small surplus on <strong>of</strong>ficial settlements.Despite <strong>the</strong> surplus on <strong>of</strong>ficial settlements, net gold sales continued asforeign monetary authorities reduced <strong>the</strong>ir dollar claims on <strong>the</strong> UnitedStates. While sales to France were $601 million in 1966, <strong>the</strong> net reductionin <strong>the</strong> U.S. gold stock for <strong>the</strong> year was $571 million.Full data on <strong>the</strong> U.S. balance <strong>of</strong> payments are available only for <strong>the</strong> firstthree quarters <strong>of</strong> 1966. Unless o<strong>the</strong>rwise noted, all figures for 1966 usedbelow represent <strong>the</strong> total <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se first three quarters at a seasonally adjustedannual rate.The structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> payments in 1965 and 1966 was markedlydifferent from that <strong>of</strong> previous years. The surplus on goods and services,which had been rising from 1959 to 1964, dropped sharply in 1965 and1966. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, <strong>the</strong> net outflow on capital account was alsogreatly reduced in both years (Chart 16 and Table 30).These developments can in large measure be attributed to (1) <strong>the</strong> increasein <strong>the</strong> direct costs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> war in Vietnam, (2) <strong>the</strong> sharp rise in importsinduced by <strong>the</strong> rapid economic expansion and <strong>the</strong> heightened pressure ondomestic resources, (3) <strong>the</strong> exceptionally tight monetary conditions <strong>of</strong> 1966,and (4) <strong>the</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> payments programs inaugurated in 1965. The lasttwo factors were important in accomplishing a large reduction in U.S. banklending abroad and in attracting an exceptional inflow <strong>of</strong> foreign capital.The Balance on Goods and ServicesThe U.S. surplus on goods and services more than doubled from 1960 to1964, reaching an exceptional peak <strong>of</strong> $8/ 2 billion. Subsequently, however,<strong>the</strong> surplus declined. As <strong>the</strong> combined result <strong>of</strong> a narrowing trade surplusand sharply increased military expenditures in 1966, it fell to $5/ 2 billion.Trade. The trade surplus fell through <strong>the</strong> first three quarters <strong>of</strong> 1966,to <strong>the</strong> lowest level since 1959. The most striking factor in this deterioration179


Chart 16U.S. Balance <strong>of</strong> International PaymentsBILLIONS OF DOLLARS- EXPORTS AND IMPORTS OF GOODS AND SERVICES40EXPORTS30IMPORTS200I I I I I I1958 1960 1962 1964 1966^/10CAPITAL FLOWSFOREIGN-10U.S. PRIVATE1 1 J | | I1958 1960 1962 1964 1966 J/10BALANCEOFFICIAL RESERVE TRANSACTIONS BASIS010^mmmmmmmmLIQUIDITY BASISIii II II—I1958 1960 1962 1964 1966^J/FIRST 3 QUARTERS AT SEASONALLY ADJUSTED ANNUAL RATES.J/EXCLUDING OFFICIAL RESERVE TRANSACTIONS.i/EXCLUDING LIQUID CAPITAL.SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE.180


TABLE 30.—United States balance <strong>of</strong> payments, 1960-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Type <strong>of</strong> transaction 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966»Balance on goods and services_Balance on merchandise trade-Military expenditures, netBalance on o<strong>the</strong>r services4.04.8-2.72.05.65.4-2.62.85.14.4-2.43.15.95.1-2.33.18.56.7-2.13.97.04.8-2.04.25.53.7-2.74.5Remittances and pensions-.7-.7-.9-1.0-1.0Government grants and capital, netU.S. private capital, netForeign nonliquid capital, netErrors and omissions-2.8-3.9.4-2.8-4.2.7-1.0-3.0-3.41.0-1.2-3.6-4.5.7-.4-3.6-6.5.7-1.0-3.4-3.7.2-.4-3.6-3.62.0-.5BALANCE ON LIQUIDITY BASIS-2.4-2.2-2.7-2.8-1.3-1.2Plus: Foreign private liquid capital, net 2Less: Increases in nonliquid liabilities t<strong>of</strong>oreign monetary authorities».51.0-.2.3.61.6.3.1.12.3.5BALANCE ON OFFICIALTRANSACTIONS BASISRESERVEGold (decrease 4)Convertible currencies (decrease -f)IMF gold tranche position (decrease -f)-.Foreign monetary <strong>of</strong>ficial claims (increase-f)-3.41.7......1.3-1.3-.1-.1.7-2.7.9( 4 ) .61.2-2.0.5-.11.7-1.5.1-.2.31.4-1.31.7-.3-.1.7*.6•-.5•-1.41 First 3 quarters at seasonally adjusted annual rates, except as noted.2 Includes changes in Treasury liabilities to certain foreign military agencies during 1960-62.»Included above under foreign nonliquid capital.*Less than $50 million.* First 3 quarters at unadjusted annual rates.NOTE.—Detail will not necessarily add to totals because <strong>of</strong> rounding.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce.was <strong>the</strong> sharp acceleration in <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> merchandise imports beginningin 1965, to an annual rate <strong>of</strong> about 20 percent. In 1966, imports rose toabout 3.5 percent <strong>of</strong> GNP—<strong>the</strong> highest in <strong>the</strong> postwar period—from about3.2 percent in 1965 and an average <strong>of</strong> less than 3 percent in previous years <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> 1960's.Imports <strong>of</strong> capital goods rose by about 50 percent, and accounted formore than 20 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> increase in imports in 1966. For <strong>the</strong> secondconsecutive year <strong>the</strong>y rose sharply as a percentage <strong>of</strong> total domestic purchases<strong>of</strong> capital goods. As <strong>the</strong> increasing demand for capital goods beganto strain domestic capacity in 1965, and even more in 1966, purchasersincreasingly turned to foreign suppliers to get prompt delivery. Whileless than 3 percent <strong>of</strong> domestic requirements was imported in 1964, about9 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> increase in domestic purchases <strong>of</strong> capital equipment between1964 and 1965, and over 12 percent between 1965 and 1966, was accountedfor by additional imports. The earlier strains and pressures continued toaffect imports, especially for long lead-time items, in <strong>the</strong> second half <strong>of</strong> 1966,after <strong>the</strong> pace <strong>of</strong> over-all economic advance had moderated.181


Export performance in 1966 was healthy despite domestic demand pressures.Exports were more than 10 percent greater than in 1965, even afteradjustment for <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1965 dock strike. The U.S. share <strong>of</strong> worldexports (excluding exports to <strong>the</strong> United States) remained stable, while<strong>the</strong> U.S. share <strong>of</strong> world exports <strong>of</strong> manufactured goods rose slightly.A major source <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> strength <strong>of</strong> U.S. exports in <strong>the</strong> 1960's has been<strong>the</strong> stability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> U.S. cost-price structure, while costs and prices have beenrising elsewhere. Recent price developments in <strong>the</strong> United States, however,brought this relative improvement to a halt. Even so, unit labor costsin manufacturing have risen less rapidly in <strong>the</strong> United States during 1966than in most o<strong>the</strong>r industrial countries. On <strong>the</strong> whole, it appears that <strong>the</strong>U.S. competitive position with respect to prices and costs was essentiallyunchanged in 1966.O<strong>the</strong>r Goods and Services. Overseas military expenditures increased in1966 by more than $700 million, after having been relatively stable for severalyears. The war in Vietnam, <strong>of</strong> course, was <strong>the</strong> cause <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> increase.Expenditures in Europe still account for about 45 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total, buthave been largely <strong>of</strong>fset by purchases <strong>of</strong> U.S. military equipment and byvarious financial transactions.O<strong>the</strong>r items in <strong>the</strong> goods and services balance behaved normally. Investmentincome receipts, expanding by 6 percent, showed continuedstrength. U.S. travel expenditures abroad also continued to increase. Foreigntravel expenditures in <strong>the</strong> United States rose faster on a percentagebasis, but by less in dollar amount, than <strong>the</strong> expenditures <strong>of</strong> U.S. nationalsabroad.The deterioration <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> U.S. balance on goods and services during 1966,in summary, reflected primarily pressures stemming from <strong>the</strong> rapid advance<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> domestic economy and <strong>the</strong> foreign exchange costs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> hostilitiesin Vietnam.The Capital AccountAs shown in Table 31, net U.S. private capital outflows fell from a record$6.5 billion in 1964 to $3.7 billion in 1965 and remained essentially unchangedin 1966.U.S. Purchases <strong>of</strong> Foreign Securities. After a sharp rise in new issues <strong>of</strong>foreign securities in U.S. markets beginning in 1962, <strong>the</strong> United States inJuly 1963 imposed an Interest Equalization Tax (IET) on purchases fromforeigners <strong>of</strong> securities <strong>of</strong> issuers in developed economies o<strong>the</strong>r than Canada.The IET was designed as a partial <strong>of</strong>fset to <strong>the</strong> lower interest rates whichprevailed in U.S. capital markets as a result <strong>of</strong> better organization andgreater competitiveness, and <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> need for <strong>the</strong> United States to presstoward full employment <strong>of</strong> its resources through expansionary fiscal andmonetary policies.The IET has worked well. From 1964 through 1966, U.S. net purchases<strong>of</strong> foreign securities averaged about $700 million annually, down182


TABLE 31.—United States balance <strong>of</strong> payments: Capital transactions, 1960-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Type <strong>of</strong> capital transaction19601961196219631964196519661U.S. private capital, net-3.9-4.2-3.4-4.5-6.5-3.7-3.6Direct investment-New foreign security issues. __O<strong>the</strong>r transactions in foreign securities 2__U.S. bank claimsO<strong>the</strong>r claims _-1.7-.6-.1-1.2-.4—1.6-.5-.2-1.3-.6—1.7-1.1.1—.5-.4-2.0-1.3.1—1.5.2-2.4-1.1.4-2.5-1.0-3.4-1.2.4.1.3-3.2-1.2.7.3-.3Foreign nonliquid capital, netDirect investmentU.S. securities (excluding Treasuryissues) __Long-term U.S. bank liabilities. .O<strong>the</strong>r*.4.1.3( 3 ).7.1.3(3) .31.0.1.1( 3 ) .8( 3 ).7.3.1.4( 3 ).7-.1.2.5.2.1-.4.2.42.0-.11.1.8.3Foreign nonliquid capital, netPlus: Foreign private liquid capital, netLess: Increases in nonliquid liabilities to foreignmonetary authorities 5Equals: Foreign capital excluding <strong>of</strong>ficial reservetransactions, net0.4.5.80.71.01.71.0-.2.3.5( 3 )0.7.61.30.71.6.31.90.2.1.1.22.02.3.53.91 First 3 quarters at seasonally adjusted annual rates.2 Includes redemptions.3 Less than $50 million.4 Includes certain special government transactions.5 Included above under foreign nonliquid capital.NOTE.—Detail will not necessarily add to totals because <strong>of</strong> rounding.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce.from <strong>the</strong> average <strong>of</strong> $1.1 billion <strong>of</strong> 1962 and 1963. U.S. purchases <strong>of</strong> newissues have stabilized near $1.2 billion; virtually all new issues have beenby Canadians and o<strong>the</strong>r borrowers not covered by <strong>the</strong> tax.U.S. Direct Investment and Bank Lending. The outflow <strong>of</strong> direct investmentfunds from <strong>the</strong> United States began to accelerate in 1963.By 1965, <strong>the</strong> flow was more than double that in 1960-62. The years 1963and 1964 also saw a sharp rise in loans abroad by U.S. banks. The totaloutflow <strong>of</strong> U.S. capital in 1964 was more than $2^2 billion in excess <strong>of</strong> itsaverage in 1960-61.Although <strong>the</strong> outflow <strong>of</strong> portfolio capital and bank loans is largely explainedby differentials in <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> borrowing and <strong>the</strong> efficiency <strong>of</strong> U.S.financial markets, <strong>the</strong> increase in direct foreign investment by U.S. corporationsin <strong>the</strong> last few years is somewhat more difficult to explain. Therapid increase in investment in Europe generally reflects, <strong>of</strong> course, a desireto participate in a large and rapidly expanding new market.Earnings on investments in Europe, however, have fallen since 1962.Between 1955 and 1962, rates <strong>of</strong> return on investments <strong>of</strong> U.S. manufacturingaffiliates in Europe, at 14 to 19 percent, were significantly highereach year than <strong>the</strong> 10 to 15 percent earned by U.S. manufacturers at home.However, since 1962, earnings on direct investments in Europe have variedbetween 12 and 14 percent, about <strong>the</strong> same as, or—in 1965—even below,183


those in <strong>the</strong> United States. It is possible that long-term plans for expansion<strong>of</strong> foreign operations decided upon in <strong>the</strong> earlier period have dictated <strong>the</strong>large investment outflows <strong>of</strong> recent years.Whatever <strong>the</strong> reasons for <strong>the</strong> sharp increase in direct investment and banklending in 1963-64, it clearly was imposing an intolerable strain on <strong>the</strong> U.S.balance <strong>of</strong> payments.Consequently, early in 1965, <strong>the</strong> United States introduced a program <strong>of</strong>voluntary restraint on foreign investment by U.S. corporations and banks.This program was designed to moderate <strong>the</strong> capital outflow to <strong>the</strong> developedcountries, while not interfering with <strong>the</strong> flow to <strong>the</strong> less developed.The Federal Reserve program requested that banks limit <strong>the</strong>ir increasein claims on foreigners in 1965 to 5 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> outstanding claims at <strong>the</strong>start <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year; a fur<strong>the</strong>r 4 percent increase was <strong>the</strong> suggested limit in 1966.Banks were asked to give priority to export financing and credits to lessdeveloped countries. Similar guidelines were applied to foreign lendingby o<strong>the</strong>r financial institutions. This program—toge<strong>the</strong>r with <strong>the</strong> effects<strong>of</strong> tight money—achieved a $2j/2 billion favorable swing in bank lendingfrom 1964 to 1965 and a fur<strong>the</strong>r $200 million improvement in 1966.The Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, early in 1965, asked large nonfinancialcorporations to make a maximum effort to expand <strong>the</strong>ir net paymentsbalances and to repatriate liquid funds. Late in 1965, corporations wereasked to limit <strong>the</strong>ir average annual direct investment outflows (includingreinvested earnings, but net <strong>of</strong> U.S. corporate borrowing abroad) for 1965-66to specified developed and oil exporting countries to no more than 135percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> average annual flow in 1962-64.Under <strong>the</strong> Commerce program, firms have been encouraged to obtainmaximum foreign financing. An indication <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> program's success is <strong>the</strong>sharp surge in U.S. corporate borrowing abroad. In particular, U.S. corporationsissued more than $500 million <strong>of</strong> securities in foreign capitalmarkets during <strong>the</strong> first three quarters <strong>of</strong> 1966. (These issues are includedin Table 31 under foreign investment in U.S. securities; it <strong>of</strong>fsets a part <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> debit on direct investment.) In addition, borrowing by foreign subsidiaries<strong>of</strong> U.S. corporations has increased, reducing <strong>the</strong> need for outflowsfrom <strong>the</strong> United States.With <strong>the</strong>se adjustments in financing, U.S. corporations continued <strong>the</strong>irextraordinary expansion <strong>of</strong> plant and equipment expenditures abroad.Outlays in 1965 were more than 20 percent higher than in 1964; a fur<strong>the</strong>rsubstantial increase is estimated for 1966, to an amount nearly double <strong>the</strong>outlays in 1962. The increase from 1965 to 1966 in U.S. manufacturinginvestment in EEC countries may have been more than one-third.Foreign Capital. Higher yields on U.S. securities in 1966 attracted a largeinflow <strong>of</strong> foreign capital, particularly into Government agency obligationsand certificates <strong>of</strong> deposit issued by U.S. banks. Foreign <strong>of</strong>ficial agencies andinternational organizations shifted a substantial volume <strong>of</strong> liquid dollarclaims into <strong>the</strong>se instruments.184


The inflow <strong>of</strong> foreign private liquid capital that occurred in <strong>the</strong> thirdquarter <strong>of</strong> 1966 was particularly large. U.S. monetary tightness provideda strong pull to such funds. Some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> inflow clearly reflected a movementout <strong>of</strong> sterling during <strong>the</strong> period <strong>of</strong> acute pressure in July and August.Although an upward trend in private foreign demand for dollar balances isto be expected, <strong>the</strong> surge that occurred in <strong>the</strong> third quarter will obviously notcontinue and may be partly reversed in <strong>the</strong> future.Most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> inflow represented borrowing by U.S. banks from <strong>the</strong>irforeign branches as <strong>the</strong> home <strong>of</strong>fices <strong>of</strong> U.S. banks responded to tightnessin <strong>the</strong>ir reserve positions. The foreign branches, able to <strong>of</strong>fer higher ratesto depositors than those allowed in <strong>the</strong> United States, ga<strong>the</strong>red a substantialvolume <strong>of</strong> short-term funds abroad. Although this flow <strong>of</strong> funds did notreduce <strong>the</strong> U.S. deficit on liquidity account, it did prevent what wouldo<strong>the</strong>rwise have been a larger flow <strong>of</strong> dollars into <strong>the</strong> hands <strong>of</strong> foreign <strong>of</strong>ficialmonetary agencies, and <strong>the</strong>reby placed <strong>the</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial settlements account in substantialsurplus in <strong>the</strong> third quarter. It probably held down <strong>the</strong> loss inU.S. reserve assets at a time when <strong>the</strong>re was temporary deterioration ino<strong>the</strong>r parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> payments.iPROSPECTS AND POLICIES FOR 1967The U.S. trade surplus should resume its growth in 1967. Indeed, improvementmay have begun in <strong>the</strong> fourth quarter <strong>of</strong> 1966. Success <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>domestic economic policies described in Chapter 1 will be essential to improvement<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> trade surplus. A moderate pace and more balancedpattern <strong>of</strong> domestic economic advance should lower <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> importsto domestic income from <strong>the</strong> peak recorded in 1966. While imports growat a slower rate, export expansion should continue to be strong, givenfavorable growth rates in foreign markets and <strong>the</strong> increase in dollar earningsenjoyed by foreigners in 1966. The easing <strong>of</strong> domestic demand pressuresand more stable prices should enable U.S. producers to take full advantage<strong>of</strong> export opportunities.In addition, <strong>the</strong> U.S. Government will undertake fur<strong>the</strong>r active effortsto promote exports, in part through expanded credit facilities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Export-Import Bank. Steps are also being taken to attract a substantially largernumber <strong>of</strong> tourists to <strong>the</strong> United States. The special task force on travelwhich <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> will appoint in <strong>the</strong> near future should lay <strong>the</strong> groundworkfor a greatly intensified long-run effort in this area.Military expenditures abroad will continue to be large, although <strong>the</strong>y willprobably grow at a slower rate than in 1966. At <strong>the</strong> same time, <strong>the</strong> excess<strong>of</strong> investment income receipts over payments should show a substantialgrowth. The surplus on goods and services, <strong>the</strong>n, should improve in 1967.Just as <strong>the</strong> capital account <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> U.S. balance <strong>of</strong> payments last yearbenefited greatly from <strong>the</strong> sharp tightening <strong>of</strong> monetary conditions, relaxation<strong>of</strong> credit could create pressures in 1967 for increased private capital


outflows and reduced foreign inflows. This makes it especially importantthat <strong>the</strong> programs to limit capital outflows be continued and streng<strong>the</strong>ned.Streng<strong>the</strong>ned Voluntary ProgramsThe 1967 guidelines for <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve and <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong>Commerce voluntary restraint programs, issued last December, reflect <strong>the</strong>seconsiderations. Commercial banks by late 1966 were more than $1.2 billionunder <strong>the</strong>ir Federal Reserve guideline ceilings. To limit <strong>the</strong> potential increasein total foreign lending during 1967, <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve asked eachbank to continue to observe, throughout 1967, its existing ceiling <strong>of</strong> 109percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> claims outstanding as <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> 1964. Banks were alsoasked to use <strong>the</strong>ir leeway under <strong>the</strong> ceiling only gradually—not more thanone-fifth <strong>of</strong> it per quarter—beginning with <strong>the</strong> fourth quarter <strong>of</strong> 1966. Moreover,to assure that such credits as are extended will be devoted primarilyto <strong>the</strong> financing <strong>of</strong> exports or to meet <strong>the</strong> credit needs <strong>of</strong> developing countries,any increase in nonexport credits to developed countries is to be limitedto 10 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> leeway existing on September 30, 1966. New andgreatly simplified guidelines were also issued for nonbank financial institutions.The guidelines for <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce voluntary program torestrain direct investment outlays <strong>of</strong> business firms abroad were also streng<strong>the</strong>ned.The ceiling on direct investment outflow plus overseas retainedearnings for <strong>the</strong> average <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two years 1966-67 was lowered to 120 percent<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1962-64 average. With <strong>the</strong> streng<strong>the</strong>ned program, <strong>the</strong> total <strong>of</strong>direct investment outflows—net <strong>of</strong> borrowings abroad—and retained overseasearnings in 1967 is expected to be below <strong>the</strong> actual level now estimatedfor 1966. The program will continue to permit <strong>the</strong> expansion <strong>of</strong> U.S. plantand equipment expenditures in those countries covered to <strong>the</strong> extent that<strong>the</strong> expansion can be financed from foreign sources. It also remains a fullyvoluntary program, confined to investments in developed and oil exportingcountries.Extension <strong>of</strong> 1ETAs a fur<strong>the</strong>r measure to streng<strong>the</strong>n existing programs, <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> isrequesting a 2-year extension <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> IET, now scheduled to expire inmid-196 7, and is asking for authority to vary <strong>the</strong> effective rate <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> taxbetween zero and 2 percent a year. By present law, <strong>the</strong> tax adds 1 percentagepoint, in effect, to <strong>the</strong> annual interest costs <strong>of</strong> those foreignerssubject to <strong>the</strong> tax who borrow at long term in <strong>the</strong> United States or who sellsecurities to U.S. citizens.The discretionary authority sought by <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> would permit arapid and flexible response to changing monetary conditions at home andabroad. Although <strong>the</strong> present 1 percent rate has virtually eliminated newsecurity issues <strong>of</strong> countries which are not exempted, <strong>the</strong> current rate couldprove ineffective, if foreign countries do not lower <strong>the</strong>ir high interest rateswhile U.S. monetary conditions ease.186


BALANCE OF PAYMENTS ADJUSTMENT POLICIESAs countries grow at different rates and in different ways, paymentsimbalances are bound to arise. The adjustment policies <strong>of</strong> each countrywill directly affect not only its payments balance but its own internal economicperformance and <strong>the</strong> payments balances <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r countries. Therefore,payments adjustment should be pursued in ways compatible with eachcountry's major domestic objectives and with <strong>the</strong> broad interests <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>entire international community.REPORT ON THE ADJUSTMENT PROCESSDuring 1966, important progress was made toward developing a greaterinternational consensus on policies best suited for adjusting payments imbalances.A report by Working Party 3 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> OECD, prepared by representatives<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> ten major industrial countries, carefully explored <strong>the</strong> nature <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> adjustment process and pointed to various possibilities for improving it.The report recommended various ways <strong>of</strong> streng<strong>the</strong>ning national policyinstruments and outlined a set <strong>of</strong> informal guidelines regarding appropriateadjustment policies. In addition, it suggested a number <strong>of</strong> steps to improveadjustment procedures through greater international cooperation,including collective reviews <strong>of</strong> countries' balance <strong>of</strong> payments aims; <strong>the</strong>setting up <strong>of</strong> an "early warning" system for prompter identification andbetter diagnosis <strong>of</strong> payments imbalances; and <strong>the</strong> streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>of</strong> internationalconsultations with respect to <strong>the</strong> sharing <strong>of</strong> responsibilities foradjustment. These suggestions stemmed from <strong>the</strong> report's major conclusions,which included <strong>the</strong> following:First, countries need to formulate <strong>the</strong>ir balance <strong>of</strong> payments aims moreclearly and base <strong>the</strong>ir individual and joint policies on aims that are mutuallyconsistent as well as desirable from <strong>the</strong> viewpoint <strong>of</strong> a healthy world economy.Second, responsibility for adjustment must fall on both surplus and deficitcountries.Third, countries need to have available and make use <strong>of</strong> a wider range <strong>of</strong>policy instruments—both general and selective—and to tailor such instrumentsmore finely to <strong>the</strong> requirements <strong>of</strong> different circumstances and multiplepolicy goals. There is particular need in many cases to place greaterreliance on fiscal policies, and less on monetary policies, in achieving internaleconomic balance, because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> important international ramifications <strong>of</strong>changes in monetary policy.Fourth, <strong>the</strong> proper combination <strong>of</strong> policy instruments depends on <strong>the</strong> situationsencountered and <strong>the</strong> particular characteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> country concerned.No single policy prescription is appropriate in all cases.Fifth, countries must take continuous account <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>iractions on o<strong>the</strong>r countries. A special need for international consultationexists in <strong>the</strong> field <strong>of</strong> monetary policy to avoid inappropriate levels <strong>of</strong> interestrates.187


U.S. ADJUSTMENT POLICIESThe strategy adopted by <strong>the</strong> United States to improve its internationalpayments position can be viewed in <strong>the</strong> light <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> adjustment principlesoutlined by Working Party 3. U.S. policy has been designed to minimizeinterference with basic domestic and international objectives <strong>of</strong> thisNation and with <strong>the</strong> healthy development <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> world economy.Monetary and fiscal policies were used in 1966 to restrain demand in<strong>the</strong> light <strong>of</strong> both domestic and balance <strong>of</strong> payments considerations. TheUnited States has continued to pursue a liberal trade policy. It hasmaintained its flow <strong>of</strong> economic assistance to <strong>the</strong> less developed countries.Direct interference with international transactions has been essentiallylimited to Government transactions and restraints on <strong>the</strong> outflow <strong>of</strong> capitalto <strong>the</strong> developed countries <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> world.Policy on Goods and ServicesResort to controls over private international transactions in goods andservices has been avoided as harmful to both <strong>the</strong> United States and <strong>the</strong> worldeconomy. The long and steady progress toward trade liberalization couldwell be reversed by even "temporary" restrictions, which could threaten tobecome permanent shelters <strong>of</strong> protection for economic interest groups.Thus, U.S. actions to deal with <strong>the</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> payments problem have maintained<strong>the</strong> trend toward trade liberalization in which <strong>the</strong> United Stateshas taken strong and consistent leadership since 1934.On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, vigorous action has been taken to minimize <strong>the</strong>foreign exchange costs <strong>of</strong> U.S. Government programs. There is noprecedent for <strong>the</strong> economic and military assistance extended to foreign countriesand <strong>the</strong> military expenditures made abroad by <strong>the</strong> U.S. Governmentsince World War II. The acceptance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se responsibilities has involveda major balance <strong>of</strong> payments drain.U.S. nonmilitary foreign aid programs—which, net <strong>of</strong> loan repayments,currently amount to $3.6 billion a year—now have only a limited net balance<strong>of</strong> payments impact. This has been achieved by tying aid so far as feasibleto purchases <strong>of</strong> U.S. goods and services. Although tying is already broadlyapplied and probably cannot be usefully extended in any major degree, continuingeffort is required to assure <strong>the</strong> effectiveness <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> techniquesemployed.U.S. <strong>of</strong>fshore military expenditures have been substantial during <strong>the</strong>entire postwar period, reflecting national security requirements and commitmentsto allies in an unsettled world. The impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se expenditureson <strong>the</strong> U.S. balance <strong>of</strong> payments was reduced from a 1958 high <strong>of</strong>$3.4 billion to less than $2.9 billion in 1965; <strong>the</strong> Vietnam war caused asharp increase, to $3.6 billion, in 1966 (first three quarters at annual rate).At <strong>the</strong> same time, deliveries <strong>of</strong> military equipment sold to foreign countriesrose from about $300 million a year in 1960 to about $1.1 billion for <strong>the</strong> fullyear 1966.188


The foreign exchange costs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> security program, even excluding Vietnam,remain high. The United States is prepared to play its full part insupplying <strong>the</strong> necessary real resources for <strong>the</strong> common defense. But it seemsreasonable to expect those allied countries whose payments positions benefitfrom U.S. expenditures for <strong>the</strong> common defense to adopt measures to neutralize<strong>the</strong>ir "windfall" foreign exchange gains—especially when <strong>the</strong>ir reservepositions are strong. This could be done in many ways. Specific arrangementscould be worked out within <strong>the</strong> framework <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> alliance itself.Such arrangements could relieve strategic planning from balance <strong>of</strong> paymentsconstraints which, in <strong>the</strong> extreme, could jeopardize our nationalsecurity and that <strong>of</strong> our allies.Policy on Capital FlowsOver <strong>the</strong> years, <strong>the</strong> outflow <strong>of</strong> U.S. capital has made a major contributionto world economic growth. By providing capital to areas where it is relativelyscarce, U.S. foreign investment raises foreign incomes and <strong>of</strong>ten leadsto a more efficient use <strong>of</strong> world capital resources. U.S. direct investmenthas provided a vehicle for <strong>the</strong> spread <strong>of</strong> advanced technology and managementskills. U.S. foreign investment also has yielded handsome returns toAmerican investors and substantial investment income receipts for <strong>the</strong>balance <strong>of</strong> payments.Despite <strong>the</strong> advantages <strong>of</strong> U.S. foreign investment both to <strong>the</strong> recipientcountries and to <strong>the</strong> United States, it can—like every good thing—be overdone.And it was being overdone in <strong>the</strong> early 1960's. Just as a person mustweigh and balance opportunities for investment that will be highly pr<strong>of</strong>itablein <strong>the</strong> future against his current wants, so must a nation weigh <strong>the</strong> benefits<strong>of</strong> future foreign exchange income against current requirements. Thecosts <strong>of</strong> adjusting o<strong>the</strong>r elements in <strong>the</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> payments may be greaterthan <strong>the</strong> costs <strong>of</strong> sacrificing future investment income.It is <strong>of</strong>ten true that U.S. investment abroad generates not only a flow <strong>of</strong>investment income but also additional U.S. exports. From a balance <strong>of</strong>payments standpoint, this is an additional dividend. Yet it is also true, insome cases, that U.S. plants abroad supply markets that would o<strong>the</strong>rwisehave been supplied from <strong>the</strong> United States, with a consequent adversedirect effect on U.S. exports.It is sometimes held that <strong>the</strong> international flow <strong>of</strong> capital occurs alwaysand automatically in just <strong>the</strong> economically "correct" amount, and that anyeffort to affect this flow through government measures constitutes a subtractionfrom <strong>the</strong> economic welfare <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> country <strong>of</strong> origin, <strong>the</strong> country <strong>of</strong>receipt, and <strong>the</strong> entire world community. Such a position cannot besustained.While much <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> large flow <strong>of</strong> U.S. capital to <strong>the</strong> developed countriesis no doubt a response to a shortage <strong>of</strong> real capital <strong>the</strong>re relative to <strong>the</strong> UnitedStates, <strong>the</strong> flow is also influenced by many o<strong>the</strong>r factors. These may include240-782 O—67—13


cyclical differences in capacity utilization, differences in monetary conditionsand financial structure, speculation on exchange rates, tax advantages, andopportunities for tax evasion—none <strong>of</strong> which necessarily leads to a morerational pattern <strong>of</strong> international investment.High prospective returns on investment in a particular country mayreflect a particular choice <strong>of</strong> policies in <strong>the</strong> recipient country that is quiteunrelated to any underlying shortage <strong>of</strong> capital. If a country chooses tochannel <strong>the</strong> bulk <strong>of</strong> its private saving into low productivity uses, if it employsa tight monetary policy, if it limits access <strong>of</strong> its own nationals to its capitalmarket, it will attract foreign capital. Restraint on such capital flows may<strong>the</strong>refore merely mean that more <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> adverse effect <strong>of</strong> such domesticpolicies on economic growth will rest—as perhaps it should—on <strong>the</strong> countrythat made <strong>the</strong> policy choice.Trade restrictions may also lead to a flow <strong>of</strong> capital that would not o<strong>the</strong>rwisetake place. U.S. investment in <strong>the</strong> EEC has, at least in part, beeninduced by <strong>the</strong> desire to get within <strong>the</strong> tariff walls erected around a largeand growing market. If, however, a continued movement toward tradeliberalization may be expected, <strong>the</strong> economic justification for some part <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong>se capital flows is lessened.One major stimulant for direct investment abroad is undoubtedly <strong>the</strong>substantial advantage in technology and managerial skills which U.S. firms<strong>of</strong>ten possess. The international transfer <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se factors may be embodiedin a capital outflow independent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> relative scarcity <strong>of</strong> capital. Actionwould thus be appropriate, not necessarily to curtail <strong>the</strong> investment itself,which would interfere with <strong>the</strong> beneficial transfer <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> scarce technologyand skills, but to transfer <strong>the</strong> source <strong>of</strong> financing to <strong>the</strong> area receiving <strong>the</strong>direct investment. This, indeed, is <strong>the</strong> primary intention and <strong>the</strong> result <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> present voluntary program on direct investment.Finally, differential monetary conditions among countries can inducecapital flows. But monetary policy is an important and useful instrument<strong>of</strong> domestic stabilization and growth as well as <strong>of</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> payments adjustment.During 1960-65, U.S. monetary policy was oriented to servedomestic expansion. In 1966, it contributed to a desirable restraint oninternal demand and to an improved balance <strong>of</strong> payments. In 1967,relaxation <strong>of</strong> U.S. monetary policy has begun in order to help obtain abetter balance <strong>of</strong> internal demand. Appropriate use <strong>of</strong> restraints on capitaloutflows in such forms as <strong>the</strong> voluntary programs and <strong>the</strong> IET can usefullysupplement monetary policy in promoting domestic and international goals.In summary, it is clear that balance <strong>of</strong> payments policy should not exemptcapital flows from its compass. It is equally clear that <strong>the</strong> United Statesshould be a major capital exporter. The U.S. programs have been designedto maintain a reasonable flow <strong>of</strong> capital, especially to <strong>the</strong> less developedcountries. Given <strong>the</strong> alternatives and <strong>the</strong> need to improve its paymentsposition, <strong>the</strong> United States has restrained <strong>the</strong> outflow <strong>of</strong> capital as190


preferable to cutting essential international commitments, limiting internationaltrade, or restricting domestic—and world—economic growth.ADJUSTMENT POLICIES OF OTHER DEVELOPED COUNTRIESActions by <strong>the</strong> United States to improve its payments position cannot by<strong>the</strong>mselves assure that <strong>the</strong> world payments pattern will be ei<strong>the</strong>r sustainableor desirable from an international point <strong>of</strong> view. Such a result is only possiblethrough appropriate efforts <strong>of</strong> both deficit and surplus countries.In 1966, various o<strong>the</strong>r countries pursued policies to reduce paymentsimbalances. The most dramatic measures were taken by <strong>the</strong> United Kingdom,following renewed severe speculative attacks on <strong>the</strong> pound in <strong>the</strong>summer, which were initially met by drawings on swaps and o<strong>the</strong>r shortterminternational credit facilities cooperatively provided by <strong>the</strong> financialauthorities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> major industrial countries and <strong>the</strong> Bank for InternationalSettlements. The British increased <strong>the</strong> bank rate to 7 percent, provided astrong dose <strong>of</strong> over-all fiscal restraint, adopted selective tax measures toencourage increased productivity, and imposed a temporary freeze on wagesand prices. These measures markedly reduced <strong>the</strong> earlier deficit, and <strong>the</strong>United Kingdom may soon move into surplus.In Italy and Japan, resumption <strong>of</strong> more rapid growth in domestic economicactivity, toge<strong>the</strong>r with policies favorable to increased capital exports,succeeded in reducing payments surpluses as <strong>the</strong> year progressed. Industrialexpansion in France similarly led to a shrinkage in that country's overallsurplus as <strong>the</strong> trade balance narrowed; however, <strong>the</strong>re continued to be anet capital inflow.Germany, which had a payments deficit in 1965 for <strong>the</strong> first time in severalyears, swung back to a sizable surplus in 1966. Monetary policy was tightenedmainly to contain inflation. As a result, domestic investment slowedmarkedly, and <strong>the</strong> trade surplus increased sharply. The payments surpluswas still expanding at year end. In January 1967, Germany took a welcomestep toward monetary ease by lowering <strong>the</strong> central bank discount rate.Although somewhat reduced from <strong>the</strong> preceding year, payments imbalancescontinued large in 1966. In some countries, corrective policiesare clearly needed to prevent imbalances from growing still larger in <strong>the</strong>current year. Moreover, considerable question remains whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> pattern<strong>of</strong> adjustment in 1967 will permit a fully satisfactory rate <strong>of</strong> economic growthin <strong>the</strong> industrial countries, and an adequate flow <strong>of</strong> capital to <strong>the</strong> less developedworld.The United States will be actively pursuing policies to streng<strong>the</strong>n itspayments position in 1967. But reduction <strong>of</strong> U.S. deficits must have acounterpart in reduced surpluses or increased deficits elsewhere. If <strong>the</strong>impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> U.S. payments improvement were to fall largely on <strong>the</strong>United Kingdom or <strong>the</strong> less developed countries, <strong>the</strong> international paymentssystem would suffer ra<strong>the</strong>r than benefit. From <strong>the</strong> viewpoint <strong>of</strong> a viable


international payments pattern, consequently, <strong>the</strong>re is no real alternative: itis <strong>the</strong> countries with strong underlying payments positions and large reserveswhich must absorb a major share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> reduced U.S. and U.K.deficits. In particular, a marked reduction is needed in <strong>the</strong> chronic over-allsurplus <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> major industrial countries <strong>of</strong> Continental Europe.The surplus countries also bear a significant share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> responsibilityfor assuring that <strong>the</strong> manner in which adjustment takes place is, to <strong>the</strong> greatestextent possible, consistent with <strong>the</strong> broad objectives <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> internationaleconomic community as a whole.Most importantly, adjustment policies should not, in <strong>the</strong> aggregate, preventa healthy rate <strong>of</strong> worldwide economic growth compatible with reasonablystable price levels. In <strong>the</strong> United States, demand policies aiming at aslower rate <strong>of</strong> growth than that <strong>of</strong> 1966 are, <strong>of</strong> course, entirely appropriateon purely domestic grounds. But an even more marked slowdown in demandthan is needed for proper domestic balance would entail serious socialand economic costs at home and could risk a recession. Given <strong>the</strong> massiveweight <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> United States in <strong>the</strong> world economy, such a policy would riska slowdown in trade and economic growth on a worldwide basis.On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, <strong>the</strong> objectives <strong>of</strong> international economic expansion andpayments adjustment are simultaneously served when surplus countries withlagging internal demand take effective steps to spur <strong>the</strong> pace <strong>of</strong> economicactivity—as was, for example, true <strong>of</strong> France, Italy, and Japan during <strong>the</strong>past year. In 1967, a number <strong>of</strong> surplus countries will be in a good positionto contribute significantly to better international payments equilibrium inthis fashion, without running serious risks <strong>of</strong> engendering inflationarypressures.Surplus countries also have a special responsibility for fostering relativefreedom in international transactions. As <strong>the</strong> report <strong>of</strong> Working Party 3pointed out, it is desirable—wherever possible—that adjustment take place"through <strong>the</strong> relaxation <strong>of</strong> controls and restraints over international tradeand capital movements by surplus countries, ra<strong>the</strong>r than by <strong>the</strong> imposition<strong>of</strong> new restraints by deficit countries." In <strong>the</strong> past year, Italy and Japangenerally followed policies that facilitated capital outflows; <strong>the</strong> recentlyannounced intention <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> French Government to liberalize capital controlsis also a hopeful development. There is, however, scope for fur<strong>the</strong>rmeasures by various surplus countries to liberalize <strong>the</strong> regulations that governcapital outflows and also to ease restrictions on imports. More liberal importpolicies would both improve payments balance and counter domesticinflation.In 1966, <strong>the</strong>re was an escalation <strong>of</strong> monetary restraint. The sharp tightening<strong>of</strong> monetary policies in <strong>the</strong> United States, undertaken largely for domesticreasons, did help significantly to contain <strong>the</strong> U.S. payments deficitduring <strong>the</strong> year. Monetary action also was a key feature in <strong>the</strong> program todefend <strong>the</strong> British pound. But countries in a strong reserve position192


also placed heavy reliance on restrictive monetary policies to containdomestic demand. The net effect <strong>of</strong> all <strong>the</strong>se actions, and <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>failure <strong>of</strong> most o<strong>the</strong>r countries to take active steps to avoid monetary stringency,was a dramatic upward movement in interest rates on a worldwidebasis (Chart 17). Between September 1965 and September 1966, rateson 90-day Eurodollar deposits increased from 4.4 percent to 6.7 percent;yields on long-term international bond issues rose by more than a fullpercentage point; and <strong>the</strong>re were marked increases in long-term governmentbond yields in all major industrial countries.The extent to which <strong>the</strong> present high worldwide level <strong>of</strong> interest rates aids<strong>the</strong> process <strong>of</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> payments adjustment is doubtful. The substantialbenefit to <strong>the</strong> U.S. balance <strong>of</strong> payments from <strong>the</strong> tightening <strong>of</strong> U.S. monetaryconditions stemmed from differential monetary conditions here andabroad. The potential magnitude <strong>of</strong> such effects is reduced when surpluscountries simultaneously permit or even encourage <strong>the</strong>ir own interest ratesto rise.From <strong>the</strong> standpoint <strong>of</strong> world economic growth, it would be preferableif payments adjustment took place at a lower average level <strong>of</strong> interest ratesthan has recently prevailed. Precisely what level is appropriate is a matterthat deserves continuing international discussion.Given <strong>the</strong> key role <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> United States in international financial markets,a general easing in international monetary conditions would be greatly aidedby a lessening <strong>of</strong> monetary tightness in <strong>the</strong> United States. A move in thisdirection, already under way, will have major benefits for domestic economicbalance. But if credit relaxation were confined to <strong>the</strong> United States,it would not promote a better balance <strong>of</strong> payments adjustment ei<strong>the</strong>r forthis country or for <strong>the</strong> major surplus countries <strong>of</strong> Europe. Moreover, atleast in some important European economies, monetary easing would helpto facilitate needed domestic economic growth. It would appear, <strong>the</strong>refore,that movement toward easier credit conditions by <strong>the</strong> countries <strong>of</strong>Western Europe would promote <strong>the</strong>ir own and <strong>the</strong> general welfare. Wherenecessary for domestic reasons, demand restraint could be maintained bygreater reliance on fiscal policy.If <strong>the</strong> major surplus countries adjust mainly by permitting <strong>the</strong>ir tradesurpluses to decline, this can lead to a substantially improved trade surplusfor <strong>the</strong> United States and permit it to maintain and even augment its role asa major capital exporter. Alternatively, if <strong>the</strong> large surplus countries—andparticularly <strong>the</strong> EEC countries—wish to continue to maintain a substantialsurplus on current account, <strong>the</strong>y should assume a larger share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> responsibilityfor providing financial capital where it is needed.Some progress in this direction has, in fact, recently been made, partlyunder <strong>the</strong> spur <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> more restricted access to U.S. capital markets. Newinternational bond issues in Europe during <strong>the</strong> first three quarters <strong>of</strong> 1966,for example, were at an annual rate <strong>of</strong> about $1.4 billion—four times <strong>the</strong>193


Chart 17Interest Rates in Selected CountriesPERCENTSHORT-TERM INTEREST RATES-L/GERMANYNtf:1964 1966LONG-TERM INTEREST RATES ^7SWITZERLAND1958 1960 1962 1964 1966.S. AND U.K., 3-MONTH TREASURY BILLS; GERMANY, 3-MONTH INTERBANK LOANS; SWITZERLAND, 3-MONTH BANK DEPOSITS..S., 10-YEAR TAXABLE BONDS; U.K., WAR LOANS; GERMANY, PUBLIC AUTHORITY BONDS; SWITZERLAND,GOVERNMENT BONDS.NOTE.-DATA PLOTTED ARE ANNUAL THROUGH 1963, QUARTERLY THEREAFTER.SOURCES: TREASURY DEPARTMENT AND BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM.,• I


$360 million level in 1962, <strong>the</strong> year preceding <strong>the</strong> introduction <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> InterestEqualization Tax. It is highly desirable, however, that <strong>the</strong> surplus countriestake stronger steps to enlarge <strong>the</strong> capacity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir capital marketsand to assure an adequate volume <strong>of</strong> long-term capital exports (includingforeign aid), especially to <strong>the</strong> less developed countries.INTERNATIONAL MONETARY REFORMThe avoidance or appropriate correction <strong>of</strong> large-scale payments imbalancesis <strong>of</strong> key importance in facilitating sound world economic growth andrelatively unfettered international trade and payments. But better adjustmentalone is not sufficient to attain <strong>the</strong>se objectives.In <strong>the</strong> long run, most countries seek some steady increase in <strong>the</strong>ir internationalreserves. With growing world transactions, this has meant that<strong>the</strong>y have generally sought to have surpluses ra<strong>the</strong>r than deficits in <strong>the</strong>irbalances <strong>of</strong> payments. Obviously, however, all countries cannot attain sucha goal simultaneously. At present, only <strong>the</strong> flow <strong>of</strong> new gold into monetaryreserves can permit a steady accumulation <strong>of</strong> reserve assets by some countrieswithout corresponding deficits for o<strong>the</strong>rs.This flow <strong>of</strong> new gold has, for many years, been inadequate. For much <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> postwar period, dollars supplied through U.S. deficits served as <strong>the</strong> majorsupplement to gold in new reserve creation. For reasons already cited, however,<strong>the</strong> dollar can no longer be expected to perform this task in <strong>the</strong> sameway; nor can it be assumed that adequate new reserves will accrue in <strong>the</strong>form <strong>of</strong> automatic drawing rights at <strong>the</strong> IMF, as <strong>the</strong> byproduct <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Fund's normal lending operations. To satisfy desires for rising <strong>of</strong>ficialmonetary reserves over <strong>the</strong> longer run and to eliminate dependence <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> world economy on <strong>the</strong> vagaries <strong>of</strong> gold production, deliberate generation<strong>of</strong> new reserve assets is needed on a cooperative international basis.In 1966, significant progress was made toward setting up a mechanism forsuch deliberate reserve creation. Representatives <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> major industrialcountries known as <strong>the</strong> Group <strong>of</strong> Ten agreed that it is prudent to begin <strong>the</strong>preparation <strong>of</strong> a contingency plan now. They also agreed that deliberatereserve creation should be tailored to global needs ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> financing<strong>of</strong> individual balance <strong>of</strong> payments deficits; that decisions on <strong>the</strong> amount<strong>of</strong> reserves to be created should be made for some years ahead; and thatreserve assets should be distributed to all members <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Fund, on <strong>the</strong> basis<strong>of</strong> IMF quotas or comparable objective standards. While <strong>the</strong> negotiationsin <strong>the</strong> Group <strong>of</strong> Ten, and parallel deliberations by <strong>the</strong> Executive Directors<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Fund, did not result in complete accord on <strong>the</strong> precise form anduse <strong>of</strong> new reserve assets, <strong>the</strong> exploration <strong>of</strong> technical details producedsubstantial agreement regarding <strong>the</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> alternative "building blocks"that might be incorporated in <strong>the</strong> final contingency plan.A major accomplishment in 1966 was <strong>the</strong> initiation <strong>of</strong> a second stage <strong>of</strong>international monetary negotiations late in <strong>the</strong> year, involving joint dis-195


cussions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Executive Directors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Fund and <strong>the</strong> Deputies <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Group <strong>of</strong> Ten. It ishoped that <strong>the</strong>se meetings, which have already shown great promise, willby <strong>the</strong> time <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> next Annual Meeting <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Fund lead to a wide consensuson <strong>the</strong> key remaining points at issue.Differences <strong>of</strong> view on two <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se points already seem to be narrowing.There now appears to be a widespread feeling that <strong>the</strong> needs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> internationalmonetary system can best be served if deliberate reserve creation iseffected through <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> an entirely new reserve unit, distributedto all Fund members. At <strong>the</strong> same time, <strong>the</strong>re is increasing recognition thatsatisfactory procedures can be developed to make <strong>the</strong> new reserve asset generallyacceptable without linking its use to specified payments <strong>of</strong> gold.Probably <strong>the</strong> most important outstanding issue is <strong>the</strong> precise manner inwhich decisions on reserve creation are to be made. There is good reasonto expect, however, that this question can be resolved in a way that takesaccount <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> legitimate needs and interests <strong>of</strong> all <strong>the</strong> countries representedin <strong>the</strong> negotiations.While <strong>the</strong> progress made in <strong>the</strong> negotiations thus gives ground for considerablesatisfaction, it is also true that <strong>the</strong> need for developing a contingencyplan for deliberate reserve creation has become more urgent.One reason is that it can no longer be assumed that U.S. deficits willautomatically increase world reserves. These deficits, which for much<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> postwar period were <strong>the</strong> main element in new reserve creation, havesince <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> 1964 made no net contribution to <strong>the</strong> rise in world reserves.Indeed, in September 1966, <strong>the</strong> dollar holdings in <strong>the</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficialreserves <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r countries were actually smaller than 21 months earlier,both in absolute terms and after a rough adjustment for seasonal influences.Over this period, total U.S. gold sales to o<strong>the</strong>r countries were more thantwice as large as <strong>the</strong> accumulated U.S. balance <strong>of</strong> payments deficit on<strong>of</strong>ficial settlements. Thus, <strong>the</strong> manner in which <strong>the</strong> U.S. deficit was financedhas tended to reduce, ra<strong>the</strong>r than augment, <strong>the</strong> total <strong>of</strong> worldreserves.Second, <strong>the</strong> flow <strong>of</strong> gold into monetary channels has been sharply reducedrecently. While final estimates for 1966 are not yet available, it islikely that <strong>the</strong>re was virtually no net addition <strong>of</strong> gold to monetary reservesduring <strong>the</strong> year. In 1965, only $240 million <strong>of</strong> new gold entered into monetarystocks. This contrasts with an annual average <strong>of</strong> about $600 millionin <strong>the</strong> decade ended in 1964.Third, it is significant that <strong>the</strong> modest increase in over-all world reservesthat did occur in <strong>the</strong> recent past reflected very special circumstances. During<strong>the</strong> 21-month period from <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> 1964 through September 1966,world reserves increased by about $1.8 billion. But <strong>the</strong> largest part <strong>of</strong> thisincrease was a byproduct <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> difficulties experienced by <strong>the</strong> British pound,which caused <strong>the</strong> U.K. authorities to draw $1.4 billion from <strong>the</strong> IMF; alarge portion <strong>of</strong> this drawing, in turn, increased reserve claims on <strong>the</strong> Fund by196


o<strong>the</strong>r countries. Not only can transactions <strong>of</strong> this kind no longer be countedupon to add to world reserves as <strong>the</strong> British situation improves, but repayment<strong>of</strong> Britain's debt could actually lead to a contraction <strong>of</strong> reserves.These considerations suggest that <strong>the</strong> time when deliberately created reservesare needed may be closer at hand than is <strong>of</strong>ten realized. In anyevent, continued uncertainty regarding <strong>the</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> a contingency plan and<strong>the</strong> timing <strong>of</strong> its adoption can be a growing source <strong>of</strong> uneasiness in internationalfinancial markets and interfere with <strong>the</strong> smooth working <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>adjustment process. Clear agreement on a contingency plan, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rhand, would be a major factor in streng<strong>the</strong>ning confidence in <strong>the</strong> worldmonetary system and in reducing gold hoarding and would help lessen <strong>the</strong>tendency <strong>of</strong> countries to pursue unattainable balance <strong>of</strong> payments aims.The essential tasks for 1967 thus are to improve <strong>the</strong> process <strong>of</strong> paymentsadjustment through increased international cooperation and to move decisivelytoward establishing a mechanism for deliberate reserve creation. Thetwo tasks are intimately interwoven; success in both is necessary to providea sound climate for world economic growth and relative freedom in tradeand capital transactions, as well as to assure an adequate flow <strong>of</strong> long-termcapital from <strong>the</strong> developed to <strong>the</strong> less developed countries.197


Appendix AREPORT TO THE PRESIDENT ON THE ACTIVITIES OFTHE COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS DURING 1966199


The PRESIDENT.LETTER OF TRANSMITTALDECEMBER 31,1966.SIR: The Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers submits this report on its activitiesduring <strong>the</strong> calendar year 1966 in accordance with <strong>the</strong> requirements <strong>of</strong>Congress, as set forth in section 4(d) <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Employment Act <strong>of</strong> 1946.Respectfully,GARDNER AGKLEY, ChairmanJAMES S. DUESENBERRYARTHUR M.OKUN201


<strong>Report</strong> to <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> on <strong>the</strong> Activities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers During 1966Throughout 1966 <strong>the</strong> Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers was confronted with<strong>the</strong> challenge <strong>of</strong> analyzing <strong>the</strong> problems and opportunities <strong>of</strong> a prosperouseconomy, now at full employment for <strong>the</strong> first time in more than a decade.The problem <strong>of</strong> reconciling full employment and price stability introduced anew emphasis into every area <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Council's work—fiscal and monetaryanalysis, examination <strong>of</strong> manpower problems and <strong>of</strong> programs for efficiencyin industry, and study <strong>of</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> payments issues. Some <strong>of</strong> our specificactivities in <strong>the</strong> price area are described more fully in our Annual <strong>Report</strong>.In recent months <strong>the</strong> pressures on prices seem to have been more restrained,as economic policies have sought to turn <strong>the</strong> expansion along <strong>the</strong> path <strong>of</strong>full employment growth. The challenge for <strong>the</strong> Council in 1967 is to contributeto <strong>the</strong> shaping <strong>of</strong> policies that will maintain expansion along thatpath.COUNCIL MEMBERSHIPGardner Ackley and Arthur M. Okun continued to serve as Council membersin 1966, with Mr. Ackley as Chairman. James S. Duesenberry joined<strong>the</strong> Council on February 2, replacing Otto Eckstein who returned to hisposition as Pr<strong>of</strong>essor <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong>s at Harvard University. Messrs. Ackley,Okun, and Duesenberry are on leave from <strong>the</strong> University <strong>of</strong> Michigan, YaleUniversity, and Harvard University, respectively.Following is a list <strong>of</strong> all past Council members and <strong>the</strong>ir dates <strong>of</strong> service:NamePositionOath <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>fice dateSeparation dateEdwin G. NourseLeon H. KeyserlingJohn D. ClarkRoy BloughRobert C. TurnerArthur F. BurnsNeilH.JacobyWalter W. StewartJoseph S. Da vis _.Raymond J. SaulnierPaul W. McCrackenKarl BrandtHenry C, WallichJames Tobin ...Kermit GordonWalter W. HellerJohn P. LewisOtto EcksteinChairman .. . .Vice C hairmanActing ChairmanChairmanMember .. ..Vice C hairmanMemberMemberChairmanMemberMember. .MemberMemberChairman . ... .MemberMemberMemberMemberMemberC hairmanMember . ..MemberAugust 9,1946August 9,1946November 2,1949May 10,195CAugust 9,1946May 10,1950June 29,1950Septembers, 1952March 19,1953September 15,1953December 2,1953May 2,1955April 4,1955December 3,1956December 3,1956November 1,1958May 7,1959January 29, 1961January 29,1961January 29,1961May 17,1963September 2,1964November 1,1949.January 20,1953.February 11,1953.August 20,1952.January 20,1953.December 1,1956.February 9,1955.April 29,1955.October 31,1958.January 20,1961.January 31,1959.January 20,1961.January 20,1961.July 31,1962.December 27,1962.November 15,1964.August 31,1964.February 1,1966.203


COUNCIL STAFFAt <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> 1966, members <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Council's pr<strong>of</strong>essional staff wereHenry J. Aaron, Shirley M. Almon, G. Paul Balabanis, Guy Black, Jack W.Carlson, Donald E. Cullen, Stanley L. Friedlander, Ca<strong>the</strong>rine H. Furlong,Stephen M. Goldfeld, Frances M. James, David T. Kresge, Wilfred Lewis,Jr., David W. Lusher, Carey P. Modlin, Jr., Saul Nelson, Alfred Reifman,Frank W. Schiff, and Charles B. Warden, Jr.Each year a number <strong>of</strong> staff members who have joined <strong>the</strong> Council on atemporary basis return to <strong>the</strong>ir posts in private life or in government. Thoseleaving <strong>the</strong> Council in 1966 were John J. Arena, Stanley W. Black, JohnW. Dorsey, Jr., Theodore J. Goering, Susan J. Lepper, Paul W. MacAvoy,Benjamin A. Okner, Theodore K. Osgood, R. Robert Russell, MartinSegal, Lewis J. Spellman, and Paul J. Taubman.Continuing its practice <strong>of</strong> discussing economic developments and problemswith leading members <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economics pr<strong>of</strong>ession, <strong>the</strong> Council in 1966called on <strong>the</strong> following consultants: W. H. Locke Anderson, G. LelandBach, James T. Bonnen, William G. Bowen, William H. Branson, WilliamM. Capron, Benjamin Chinitz, Gerhard Colm, Richard N. Cooper, Peter P.Dorner, John T. Dunlop, Otto Eckstein, R. Aaron Gordon, Kermit Gordon,Walter W. Heller, Myron L. Joseph, Carl Kaysen, Stanley Lebergott,Allen H. Lerman, Harold M. Levinson, John V. Lintner, Jr., Edwin S.Mills, Richard A. Musgrave, Joseph A. Pechman, Merton J. Peck, Frank C.Pierson, George L. Perry, Albert E. Rees, Melvin Rothbaum, Paul A.Samuelson, Robert M. Solow, Daniel B. Suits, Charles A. Taff, Lester D.Taylor, Lester C. Thurow, James Tobin, and Robert C. Turner.The Council extended into <strong>the</strong> winter months its graduate student internprogram, which was started in 1961 and, until 1966, had been carried onin only <strong>the</strong> summer months. Graduate students working with <strong>the</strong> Councilfor various periods in 1966 were Arthur J. Alexander, Barry P. Bosworth,Terrence R. Colvin, Robert J. Flanagan, E. Duncan Moose, Larry B.Morse, Ralph E. Pochoda, and Kenneth R. Smith.As in <strong>the</strong> past, <strong>the</strong> Council received loyal and energetic assistance from itsnonpr<strong>of</strong>essional staff. Members <strong>of</strong> this staff at <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> 1966 wereDorothy Bagovich, Teresa D. Bradburn, Louis P. Brighthaupt, Carrie E.Bryant, Carol S. Burke, Gladys R. Durkin, Ca<strong>the</strong>rine Fibich, CharlotteFremon, James W. Gatling, Laura B. H<strong>of</strong>fman, Christine L. Johnson,Constance R. King, Bessie M. Lafakis, Patricia A. Lee, June A. Liverman,Dorothy L. Reid, Earnestine Reid, Gail Roberts, Bettye T. Siegel, Daisy M.Sindelar, Nancy F. Skidmore, Roselle Smith, Margaret L. Snyder, MaryAlice Spriggs, Miriam E. Vincent, and Elizabeth A. Zea.In 1966, as in earlier years, <strong>the</strong> Council relied upon <strong>the</strong> editorial skills<strong>of</strong> Miss Dorothy Wescott in preparing <strong>the</strong> Annual <strong>Report</strong>.204


COUNCIL ACTIVITIESThe Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers was established as an agency <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Federal Government nearly 21 years ago by <strong>the</strong> Employment Act <strong>of</strong> 1946.Under <strong>the</strong> Act, <strong>the</strong> Council is charged with <strong>the</strong> responsibility <strong>of</strong> analyzingand interpreting economic developments and <strong>of</strong> recommending economicpolicies that will promote <strong>the</strong> goals <strong>of</strong> "maximum employment, production,and purchasing power."The Council's chief responsibility is to keep <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> fully informed<strong>of</strong> economic developments and emerging problems which may affect <strong>the</strong>Nation's economy. To meet this responsibility, <strong>the</strong> Council continuouslyreviews economic conditions, undertakes special studies <strong>of</strong> particular problemareas, and makes recommendations concerning Government programsand policies. The Council confers regularly with all major Governmentagencies having responsibilities in <strong>the</strong> economic field.The Secretary <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Treasury, <strong>the</strong> Director <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Budget,and <strong>the</strong> Chairman <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Council and <strong>the</strong>ir respective staffs (<strong>the</strong> "Troika")provide <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> with a continuous joint assessment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economicand budgetary outlook for <strong>the</strong> current and subsequent fiscal years, and,where appropriate, analyze <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> alternative fiscal policies. Theheads <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> "Troika" agencies and <strong>the</strong>ir associates, toge<strong>the</strong>r with <strong>the</strong> Chairman<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System, meetperiodically as <strong>the</strong> "Quadriad" with <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> to discuss domestic andinternational monetary problems. Joint staff work among <strong>the</strong> "Quadriad"agencies contributed in 1966 to improved coordination <strong>of</strong> fiscal and monetarypolicies.In addition to its regular and informal consultations with o<strong>the</strong>r Governmentagencies, <strong>the</strong> Council and its staff in 1966 participated with o<strong>the</strong>ragencies in a large variety <strong>of</strong> more formal committees, task forces, andstudies. Although <strong>the</strong> results <strong>of</strong> most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se activities are for use onlywithin <strong>the</strong> Government, two studies in which <strong>the</strong> Council participated werepublished in 1966—<strong>the</strong> reports <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Nor<strong>the</strong>ast Desalting Team and <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Interagency Energy Study. O<strong>the</strong>r projects and studies related to suchdiverse problems as environmental pollution, income maintenance, highenergy transmission, cost effectiveness in <strong>the</strong> Federal Government, economicimpact <strong>of</strong> disarmament, manpower activities, balance <strong>of</strong> payments problems,and <strong>the</strong> operation <strong>of</strong> financial institutions.The Council and its staff represent <strong>the</strong> United States in a number <strong>of</strong>important international conferences. The Council Chairman heads <strong>the</strong>U.S. delegation to <strong>the</strong> meetings <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Policy Committee <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Organization for <strong>Economic</strong> Cooperation and Development (OECD), andmembers <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Council and its staff this year participated in a dozen ormore o<strong>the</strong>r international meetings under <strong>the</strong> auspices <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> OECD. TheChairman and Mr. Okun were members, respectively, <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> U.S. Cabinetleveldelegations which meet annually with similar delegations <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Cana-205


dian and Japanese governments. The Council also was involved in activities<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> UN <strong>Economic</strong> Commission for Europe.An important responsibility <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Council is to explain and clarify <strong>the</strong>Administration's economic policies, both within <strong>the</strong> Government and to<strong>the</strong> public at large. This is done through numerous speeches, articles,press briefings, statements, Congressional testimony, its Annual <strong>Report</strong>, andby assisting <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong> in <strong>the</strong> preparation <strong>of</strong> his <strong>Economic</strong> <strong>Report</strong>. TheCouncil meets frequently and informally with many visiting scholars, <strong>of</strong>ficials<strong>of</strong> foreign countries, men and women from <strong>the</strong> press corps, businessmen,labor leaders, State <strong>of</strong>ficials, bankers, and interested private citizens,and more formally with a number <strong>of</strong> advisory groups, including <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong>'sAdvisory Committee on Labor-Management Policy and <strong>the</strong> BusinessCouncil's Liaison Committee with <strong>the</strong> Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers.The Council prepares two documents for publication. One is <strong>the</strong> <strong>Economic</strong><strong>Report</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>President</strong>, toge<strong>the</strong>r with <strong>the</strong> Annual <strong>Report</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers. Over 70,000 copies <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1966 <strong>Report</strong>were distributed to members <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Congress, Government <strong>of</strong>ficials, <strong>the</strong>press, depository libraries, or sold to <strong>the</strong> public by <strong>the</strong> Superintendent <strong>of</strong>Documents. The second is <strong>the</strong> monthly <strong>Economic</strong> Indicators. This importantcompilation <strong>of</strong> current economic statistics has been prepared since1948 at <strong>the</strong> Council under <strong>the</strong> direction <strong>of</strong> Miss Frances M. James, and ispublished by <strong>the</strong> Joint <strong>Economic</strong> Committee <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Congress. More than9,000 copies are furnished to members <strong>of</strong> Congress, depository libraries, orsold to <strong>the</strong> public every month.206


Appendix BSTATISTICAL TABLES RELATING TO INCOME,EMPLOYMENT, AND PRODUCTION207


CONTENTSNational income or expenditure:B-l. Gross national product or expenditure, 1929-66 213B-2. Gross national product or expenditure, in 1958 prices, 1929-66 214B-3. Implicit price deflators for gross national product, 1929-66 216B-4. Gross national product by major type <strong>of</strong> product, 1929-66 218B-5. Gross national product by major type <strong>of</strong> product, in 1958 prices,1929-66 219B-6. Gross national product: Receipts and expenditures by major economicgroups, 1929-66 220B-7. Gross national product by sector, 1929-66 222B-8. Gross national product by sector, in 1958 prices, 1929-66 223B-9. Personal consumption expenditures, 1929-66 224B-10. Gross private domestic investment, 1929-66 225B-l 1. National income by type <strong>of</strong> income, 1929-66 226B-l 2. Relation <strong>of</strong> gross national product and national income, 1929-66. .. . 227B-l 3. Relation <strong>of</strong> national income and personal income, 1929-66 228B-14. Disposition <strong>of</strong> personal income, 1929-66 229B-15. Sources <strong>of</strong> personal income, 1929-66 230B-l 6. Total and per capita disposable personal income and personal consumptionexpenditures, in current and 1958 prices, 1929-66 232B-l 7. Number and money income <strong>of</strong> families and unrelated individuals,1947-65 233B-18. Sources and uses <strong>of</strong> gross saving, 1929-66 234Population, employment, wages, and productivity:B-l9. Population by age groups: Estimates, 1929-66, and projections,1970-85 235B-20. Noninstitutional population and <strong>the</strong> labor force, 1929-66 236B—21. Civilian employment and unemployment, by sex and age, 1947—66. . . 238B-22. Selected unemployment rates, 1948-66 239B-23. Unemployment by duration, 1947-66 240B-24. Unemployment insurance programs, selected data, 1940-66 241B-25. Number <strong>of</strong> wage and salary workers in nonagricultural establishments,1929-66 242B-26. Average weekly hours <strong>of</strong> work in selected industries, 1929-66 244B-27. Average gross hourly earnings in selected industries, 1929-66 245B-28. Average gross weekly earnings in selected industries, 1929-66 246B-29. Average weekly hours and hourly earnings, gross and excluding overtime,in manufacturing industries, 1939-66 247B-30. Average weekly earnings, gross and spendable, in manufacturingindustries, in current and 1957-59 prices, 1939-66 248B-31. Indexes <strong>of</strong> output per man-hour and related data, private economy,1947-66 249Page209


Production and business activity:PageB-32. Industrial production indexes, major industry divisions, 1929-66. . . . 250B-33. Industrial production indexes, market groupings, 1947-66 251B-34. Industrial production indexes, selected manufactures, 1947-66 252B-35. Manufacturing capacity, output, and utilization rate, 1948-66 253B-36. New construction activity, 1929-66 254B-37. New housing starts and applications for financing, 1929-66 256B-38. Business expenditures for new plant and equipment, 1939 and 1945-67 258B-39. Sales and inventories in manufacturing and trade, 1947-66 259R-40. Manufacturers' shipments and inventories, 1947-66 260B-41. Manufacturers' new and unfilled orders, 1947-66 261Prices:B-42. Consumer price indexes, by major groups, 1929-66 262B-43. Consumer price indexes, by special groups, 1935-66 263B-44. Wholesale price indexes, by major commodity groups, 1929-66 264B-45. Wholesale price indexes, by stage <strong>of</strong> processing, 1947-66 266Money supply, credit, and finance:B-46. Money supply, 1947-66 , 268B-47. Selected liquid assets held by <strong>the</strong> public, 1946-66 269B-48. Financial saving by individuals, 1939-66 270B-49. Bank loans and investments, 1929-66 271B-50. Bond yields and interest rates, 1929-66 272B-51. Federal Reserve Bank credit and member bank reserves, 1929-66 274B-52. Short- and intermediate-term consumer credit outstanding, 1929-66.. 275B-53. Instalment credit extended and repaid, 1946-66 276B-54. Mortgage debt outstanding, by type <strong>of</strong> property and <strong>of</strong> financing,1939-66 277B-55. Net public and private debt, 1929-66 278Government finance:B-56. U.S. Government debt, by kind <strong>of</strong> obligation, 1929-66 279B-57. Estimated ownership <strong>of</strong> U.S. Government obligations, 1939-66 280B-58. Average length and maturity distribution <strong>of</strong> marketable interest-bearingpublic debt, 1946-66 281B-59. Federal administrative budget receipts by source and expenditures byfunction, fiscal years 1939-68 282B^60. Federal administrative budget receipts and expenditures and <strong>the</strong>public debt, 1929-68 284B-61. Government cash receipts from and payments to <strong>the</strong> public, 1946-68.. 285B-62. Government receipts and expenditures in <strong>the</strong> national income andproduct accounts, 1929-66 286B-63. Federal Government receipts and expenditures in <strong>the</strong> national incomeand product accounts, 1946-68 287B-64. Relation <strong>of</strong> three measures <strong>of</strong> Federal Government receipts and expenditures,fiscal years 1964-68 288B-65. State and local government revenues and expenditures, selected fiscalyears, 1927-65 289210


Corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its and finance: PageB-66. Pr<strong>of</strong>its before and after taxes, all private corporations, 1929-66 290B-67. Sales, pr<strong>of</strong>its, and stockholders' equity, all manufacturing corporations(except newspapers), 1947-66 291B-68. Relation <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its after taxes to stockholders' equity and to sales,all manufacturing corporations (except newspapers), by industrygroup, 1947-66 292B-69. Sources and uses <strong>of</strong> funds, nonfarm nonfinancial corporate business,1955-66 294B-70. Current assets and liabilities <strong>of</strong> United States corporations, 1939-66. . 295B-71. State and municipal and corporate securities <strong>of</strong>fered, 1934-66 296B-72. Common stock prices, earnings, and yields, and stock market credit,1939-66 297B-73. Business formation and business failures, 1929-66 298Agriculture:B-74. Income from agriculture, 1929-66 299B-75. Farm production indexes, 1929-66 300B-76. Farm population, employment, and productivity, 1929-66 301B-77. Indexes <strong>of</strong> prices received and prices paid by farmers, and parity ratio,1929-66 302B-78. Selected measures <strong>of</strong> farm resources and inputs, 1929-66 304B^-79. Comparative balance sheet <strong>of</strong> agriculture, 1929-67. 305International statistics:B-80. United States balance <strong>of</strong> payments, 1947-66 306B-81. United States merchandise exports and imports, by commodity groups,1958-66 308B**82. United States merchandise exports and imports, by area, 1960-66. . . 309fr-83. United States foreign assistance, by type and area, fiscalyears 1946-^66. 310B-84. International reserves, 1949, 1953, and 1961-66 311B-85. United States gold stock and holdings <strong>of</strong> convertible foreign currenciesby U.S. monetary authorities, 1946-66 312B-86. Price changes in international trade, 1958-66 313B-87. Consumer price indexes in <strong>the</strong> United States and o<strong>the</strong>r major industrialcountries, 1960-66 314General NotesDetail in <strong>the</strong>se tables will not necessarily add to totals because <strong>of</strong> rounding.Data for Alaska and Hawaii are not included unless specifically noted.Unless o<strong>the</strong>rwise noted, all dollar figuresare in current prices.Symbols used:* Preliminary... Not available (also, not applicable).* Amount insignificant in terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> particular unit (e.g., less than$50 million where unit is billions <strong>of</strong> dollars).211


NATIONAL INCOME OR EXPENDITURETABLE B-l.—Gross national product or expenditure, 7929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year or quarterTotalgrossnationalproductPersonalconsump-expend-itures lGrossprivatedomesticinvestment2Netexports<strong>of</strong> goodsandservices3Governrnent purehases <strong>of</strong> goods and servicesTotalTotalFederal *Nationaldefense 5O<strong>the</strong>rStateandlocal1929103.177.216.21.18.51.31.37.2193019311932 ._193319341935193619371938 .-193990.475.858.055.665.172.282.590.484.790.569.960.548.645.851.355.761.966.563.966.810.35.61.01.43.36.48.511.86.59.31.0.5.4.4.6.1.1.31.31.19.29.28.18.09.810.012.011.913.013.31.41.51.52.03.02.94.94.75.45.11.41.51.52.03.02.94.94.75.41.23.97.87.76.66.06.87.17.07.27.68.2194019411942 ..1943194419451946194719481949 ..99.7124.5157.9191.6210.1211.9208.5231.3257.6256.570.880.688.599.3108.3119.7143.4160.7173.6176.813.117.99.85.77.110.630.634.046.035.71.71.3-2.0-1.8-.67.511.56.46.114.024.859.688.696.582.327.025.131.637.86.016.951.981.189.074.217.212.516.520.12.213.849.479.787.473.514.79.110.713.33.83.12.51.41.6.72.53.55.86.88.07.97.77.47.58.19.812.615.017.71950195119521953 . -.1954 -.195519561957 . ...1958 --.1959284.8328.4345.5364.6364.8398.0419.2441.1447.3483.7191.0206.3216.7230.0236.5254.4266.7281.4290.1311.254.159.351.952.651.767.470.067.860.975.31.83.72.2.41.82.04.05.72.2.137.959.174.781.674.874.278.686.194.297.018.437.751.857.047.444.145.649.553.653.714.133.645.948.741.238.640.344.245.946.04.34.15.98.46.25.55.35.37.77.619.521.522.924.627.430.133.036.640.643.3196019611962—196319641965 . _.1966 *»503.7520.1560.3590.5631.7681.2739.5325.2335.2355.1375.0401.4431.5465.074.871.783.087.193.0106.6116.54.05.65.15.98.57.04.999.6107.6117.1122.5128.9136.2153.153.557.463.464.265.266.877.044.947.851.650.850.050.160.08.69.611.813.515.216.717.046.150.253.758.263.769.476.2Seasonally adjusted annual rates1964: IIIIIIIV_. _.616.8627.7637.9644.2391.1398.0407.5408.890.291.892.597.49.07.98.48.6126.5130.1129.5129.464.966.665.164.150.151.649.848.514.815.115.315.661.663.464.465.31965: III.IllIV660.8672.9686.5704.4418.9426.8435.0445.2103.8103.7106.7111.96.48.27.16.1131.6134.3137.7141.264.465.667.569.848.249.150.752.516.216.516.817.367.368.770.271.41966: IIIIII. .IV P721.2732.3745.3759.1455.6460.1469.9474.4114.5118.5115.0118.06.04.74.24.8145.0149.0156.2161.971.974.079.082.554.657.162.065.517.416.917.017.073.175.077.279.41 See Table B-9 for major components.2 See Table B-10 for fur<strong>the</strong>r detail and explanation <strong>of</strong> components.3 See Table B-6 for exports and imports separately.4 Net <strong>of</strong> Government sales.5 This category corresponds closely to <strong>the</strong> national defense classification in <strong>the</strong> Budget <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> United StatesGovernment for <strong>the</strong> Fiscal Year ending June SO, 1968.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.213


TABLE B-2.—Gross national product or expenditure, in 1958 prices, 1929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars, 1958 prices]Year orquarter19291930193119321933193419351936193719381939194019411942194310441945194619471948-19491950195119521953195419551956195719581959196019611962196319641965-1966 v1964: I II—III—IV...1965: I II—III...IV...1966: I II—III—IV P..Totalgrossnationalproduct203.6183.5169.3144.2141.5154.3169.5193.0203.2192.9209.4227.2263.7297.8337.1361.3355.2312.6309.9323.7324.1355.3383.4395.1412.8407.0438.0446.1452.5447.3475.9487.7497.2529.8551.0580.0614.4647.7569.7578.1585.0587.2600.3607.8618.2631.2640.5643.5649.9657.0Personal consumptionexpendituresTotal139.6130.4126.1114.8112.8118.1125.5138.4143.1140.2148.2155.7165.4161.4165.8171.4183.0203.5206.3210.8216.5230.5232.8239.4250.8255.7274.2281.4288.2290.1307.3316.1322.5338.4353.3373.8396.2415.5365.7371.0379.5378.9387.1392.2398.9406.5412.8412.2418.3418.5Durablegoods16.312.911.28.48.39.411.714.515.112.214.516.719.111.710.29.410.620.524.726.328.434.731.530.835.335.443.241.041.537.943.744.943.949.253.759.166.470.857.259.560.958.864.864.267.269.272.268.571.671.2Nondurablegoods69.365.965.660.458.662.565.973.476.077.181.284.689.991.393.797.3104.7110.8108.3108.7110.5114.0116.5120.8124.4125.5131.7136.2138.7140.2146.8149.6153.0158.2162.2170.5178.2185.9Services54.051.549.445.946.046.147.950.552.050.952.554.456.358.561.864.767.772.173.475.877.681.884.887.891.194.899.3104.1108.0112.0116.8121.6125.6131.1137.4144.2151.6158.7Gross private domestic investmentTotal40.427.416.84.75.39.418.024.029.917.024.733.041.621.412.714.019.652.351.560.448.069.370.060.561.259.475.474.368.860.973.672.469.079.482.586.597.8104.3Fixed investmentTotal36.928.019.210.99.712.115.620.924.519.423.528.132.017.312.915.922.642.351.755.951.961.059.057.260.261.469.069.567.662.468.868.967.073.476.781.989.093.7NonresidentialTotal26.521.714.18.27.69.211.515.818.813.715.318.922.212.510.013.419.830.236.238.034.537.539.638.340.739.643.947.347.441.644.147.145.549.751.957.464.972.2Structures13.911.87.54.43.33.64.05.47.15.65.96.88.14.62.93.85.712.511.612.311.912.714.113.714.915.216.218.518.216.616.217.417.417.917.918.921.723.5Seasonally adjusted annual rates167.2168.4173.3173.1174.2177.6178.5182.5184.1185.8187.1186.5141.2143.1145.3146.9148.1150.4153.1154.8156.5157.9159.6160.984.685.685.790.295.995.397.9102.2103.5106.3102.5105.081.281.682.282.886.688.089.491.995.094.793.591.755.556.658.259.262.363.465.568.470.871.373.073.818.718.918.719.220.721.721.323.224.323.623.223.0Producers'durableequipment12.69.96.63.84.35.67.510.311.88.19.412.114.27.97.29.614.117.724.625.722.624.825.524.625.824.527.728.829.125.027.929.628.131.734.038.543.248.736.737.739.540.041.541.744.245.246.447.749.850.8Residentialstructures10.46.35.12.72.12.94.05.15.65.78.29.29.84.92.92.52.812.115.417.917.423.519.518.919.621.725.122.220.220.824.721.921.623.824.824.624.121.525.724.924.123.624.424.523.923.524.323.420.517.9Changein businessinventories3.5-.6-2.4-6.2-4.3-2.72.43.15.5-2.41.24.99.64.0-.2-1.9-2.910.0-.24.6-3.98.310.93.3.9-2.06.44.81.2-1.54.83.52.06.05.84.68.810.63.54.03.57.49.37.38.510.28.511.69.113.2See footnote at end <strong>of</strong> table.214


TABLE B-2.—Gross national product or expenditure, in 1958 prices, 1929-66—Continued[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars, 1958 prices]Year or quarterNet exports <strong>of</strong> goods and servicesNetexportsExportsImportsGovernment purchases <strong>of</strong> goods andservicesTotalFederal iState andlocal19291.511.810.322.03.518.519301931 _ . _19321933193419351936193719381939 —1.4.9.6.3-1.0-1.2-.71.91.310.48.97.17.17.37.78.29.89.910.09.07.96.67.17.18.79.310.58.08.724.325.424.223.326.627.031.830.833.935.24.04.34.66.08.07.912.211.513.312.520.221.119.617.318.619.219.619.420.622.719401941194219431944194519461947194819492.1.4-2.1-5.9-5.8-3.88.412.36.16.411.011.27.86.87.610.219.622.618.118.18.910.89.912.613.413.911.210.312.011.736.456.3117.1164.4181.7156.448.439.946.353.315.036.298.9147.8165.4139.730.119.123.727.621.420.118.316.616.316.718.420.822.725.719501951195219531954195519561957 -..19581959 . .2.75.33.01.13.03.25.06.22.2.316.319.318.217.818.820.924.226.223.123.813.614.115.216.715.817.719.119.920.923.552.875.492.199.888.985.285.389.394.294.725.347.463.870.056.850.749.751.753.652.527.527.928.429.732.134.435.637.640.642.21960196119621963196419651966*4.35.14.55.68.56.34.827.328.030.032.136.437.341.323.022.925.526.628.031.036.494.9100.5107.5109.6111.3114.1123.251.454.660.059.557.857.864.143.545.947.550.153.456.359.1Seasonally adjusted annual rates1964: IIIIIIIV9.28.28.48.036.135.736.737.126.927.528.329.0110.3113.3111.3110.158.259.757.456.152.053.653.954.01965: I..IIIIIIV5.77.16.46.033.438.738.438.7-27.731.631.932.8111.5113.2115.0116.656.257.358.359.355.355.956.757.31966: III . _ . _IIIIV P5.94.64.24.740.140.341.842.934.235.837.638.2118.3120.4124.9128.860.461.965.568.257.958.559.460.61 Net <strong>of</strong> Government sales.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.215


TABLE B-3.—Implicit price deflators for gross national product, 1929-66llndex numbers, 1958=100]Year or quarter1929193019311932 .. _193319341935 . . -193619371938 „19391940 .194119421943 ..1944194519461947 . _ . .19481949195019511952...195319541955 -19561957196819591960 - - --19611962 .--19631964 .19651966*.1964: I II . . ._IllIV1965: I .-IIIIIIV....1966: I IIIIIIV*Totalgrossationalproduct150.649.344.840.239.342.242.642.744.543.943.243.947.253.056.858.259.766.774.679.679.180.285.687.588.389.690.994.097.5100.0101.6103.3104.6105.8107.2108.9110.9114.2108.3108.6109.1109.7110.1110.7111.0111.6112.6113.8114.7115.6Personal consumptionTotal55.353.647.942.340.643.544.444.746.545.-645.145.548.754.859.963.265.470.577.982.381.782.988.690.591.792.592.894.897.7100.0101.3102.9103.9104.9106.1107.4108.9111.9107.0107.3107.4107.9108.2108.8109.0109.5110.4111.8112.3113.4expendituresDurablegoods56.455.349.143.241.944.743.743.645.846.746.046.550.459.364.271.575.976.882.786.386.887.894.295.494.392.991.994.998.4100.0101.4100.9100.6100.8100.4100.499.598.0100.6100.5100.3100.1100.5100.299.298.497.598.098.298.6Nondurablegoods54.551.644.137.738.042.744.544.846.444.043.243.847.755.662.566.268.774.383.688.585.686.093.394.393.994.293.694.997.7100.099.9101.2101.9102.8104.0104.9107.0110. d104.6104.8104.9105.4106.0106.7107.2107.9109.6110.7111.2111.9Services56.155.752.748.343.644.344.445.046.847.747.747.949.852.755.357.558.762.767.972.174.376.380.083.687.790.092.094.697.3100.0103.0105.8107.6109.0110.9113.2115.3119.4112.3112.9113.3114.0114.3115.0115.5116.4117.2118.7120.0121.6Gross private domestic investment *Fixed investmentTotal39.437.935.231.630.633.734.334.637.838.237.739.042.046.549.351.151.558.566.773.974.777.583.185.386.686.889.094.098.5100.0102.6103.4103.9104.9106.0107.8109.6112.1106.7107.4108.1108.7109.0109.2109.6110.4111.1112.1112.5112.9NonresidentialTotal39.938.135.832.931.634.935.935.638.839.338.740.042.747.849.951.051.056.364.570.772.874.480.482.684.084.886.792.497.9100.0102.2102.9103.4104.1104.5105.8107.4109.8104.8105.5106.1106.9107.1107.1107.2108.0108.8109.7110.0110.7Structures35.734.031.127.627.928.930.630.234.433.933.133.936.441.346.848.649.254.464.471.571.272.979.383.284.986.088.193.498.6100.0102.7104.0105.6107.1108.9111.3114.4118.8108.4110.6112.6113.6113.7113.6114.6115.5117.1118.3119.4120.4Producers'durableequipment44.643.041.139.134.538.838.738.541.443.042.243.446.351.551.151.951.757.564.670.373.675.280.982.283.584.085.991.897.5100.0102.0102.2102.1102.3102.3103.1103.8105.5103.0102.9103.0103.6103.8103.8103.6104.1104.5105.4105.6106.3Residentialstructures38.137.133.627.327.130.129.831.334.335.535.736.940.343.347.051.654.959.771.780.878.582.588.690.891.990.492.997.499.8100.0103.1104.5105.0106.7108.9112.3115.5120.0110.9111.9113.0113.4113.8114.5116.4117.3117.7119.6121.3122.2See footnotes at end <strong>of</strong> table.2l6


TABLE B-3.—Implicit price deflators for gross national product, 1929-66—Continued[Index numbers, 1958=100]Year or quarterExports and imports <strong>of</strong>goods and services 1ExportsImportsGovernment purchases <strong>of</strong> goodsand servicesTotalFederalState andlocalGross national productby sectorsPrivate 2Generalgovernment192959.557.338.636.039.151.734.119301931193219331934 . _ .193519361937 . .1938.1939-..52.341.034.733.740.642.343.446.543.844.149.039.331.528.833.636.036.740.737.938.637.936.333.434.536.837.037.638.438.337.934.134.531.933.137.437.040.540.740.540.838.736.633.835.036.637.035.937.136.836.350.445.740.939.943.043.543.445.344.643.934.134.533.733.534.834.736.536.537.436.819401941 - _194219431944194519461947 —_ -_1948194948.653.061.565.269.971.375.487.392.787.040.843.048.351.253.256.464.979.486.482.238.544.050.953.953.152.655.862.968.171.040.246.652.554.953.853.157.365.669.873.037.339.242.344.646.148.653.260.466.468.944.748.755.560.962.062.668.276.381.480.636.034.737.339.743.348.355.458.560.864.7195019611952195319541955195619571958195984.997.098.895.294.394.997.5101.3100.098.888.7107.2103.699.1100.8100.6102.5104.0100.099.371.878.581.081.884.187.192.196.4100.0102.472.979.481.281.483.586.991.795.8100.0102.270.876.980.682.885.387.592.797.3100.0102.681.487.489.089.690.891.694.597.9100.0101.467.170.574.476.679.584.088.793.3100.0104.21960196119621963196419651966 999.9101.9100.8100.6101.5104.5103.9101.0100.198.599.5101.9103.3104.2105.0107.1109.0111.8115.8119.4124.3104.2105.2105.6108.0112.7115.7120.1105.9109.4113.2116.3119.3123.2128.9102.8103.7104.7105.8107.1108.9111.7108.6113.6116.6121.5128.1133.3140.71964: I11IllIV101.0100.7101.4102.9101.9102.2101.6101.8114.7114.8116.3117.5111.4111.6113.4114.3118.4118.3119.5120.8106.6106.9107.2107.8126.5127.1128.7130.11965: I11IIIIV106.0104.7104.5103.9103.5102.2103.4104.2118.0118.7119.7121.1114.4114.6115.8117.8121.6122.8123.7124.6108.2108.8109.0109.4131.0131.8133.7136.51966: I11IIIIV *103.9103.9103.9103.9104.2104.2104.2104.2122.6123.7125.0125.8119.1119.6120.5121.0126.3128.0129.9131.1110.3111.5112.2113.0138.6139.3141.6143.21 Separate deflators are not available for total gross private domestic investment, change in businessinventories, and net exports <strong>of</strong> goods and services.2 Gross national product less compensation <strong>of</strong> general government employees. See also Tables B-7 andB-8.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.217


TABLE B-4.—Gross national product by major type <strong>of</strong> product, 1929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year orquarterTotalgrossnationalproductFinal InventorychangeTotalgoodsGoods outputTotalFinalDurable goodsNondurable goodsTotal Finalsales |l Total FinalServicesStructures19291930193119321933193419351936193719381939194019411942194319441945194619471948194919501951195219531954195519561957195819591960196119621963196419651966*1964: I—II—III.IV-1965: I—II-III..IV..1966: I—II-III.IV*103.190.475.858.055.665.172.282.590.484.790.599.7124.157.9191.6210.1211.9208.5231.3257.6256.5284.8328.4345.5364.6364.8398.0419.441.1447.3483.503.520.1560.590.5631.681.739.5101.490.777.060.57.265.871.81.287.985.690.197.5120.1156.:192.211.1213.0202.1231.8252.9259.6278.0318.1342.4364.1366.392.0414.5439.8448.8478.9500.2518.1554.3584.6627.0672.1728.11.7-.4-1.1-2.5-1.6-.71.11.32.5-.9.42.4.51.8-.6-1.0-1.06.4-.54.7-3.16.810.33.16.04.71.3-1.54.83.62.06.05.94.79.111.56.146.937.426.727.034.439.945.851.545.349.056.072.593.6120.4132.3128.9124.9139.7154.2147.5162.4189.7195.6204.1197.1216.4225.4234.6230.8249.1259.6262.3284.5298.6318.344.7376.754.347.338.629.228.635.138.844.548.946.48.653.868.091.9121.0133.3129.9118.5140.1149.4150.5155.6179.4192.5203.7198.6210.220.7233.3232.244.4256.0260.2278.5292.7313.6335.7365.1.7-.4-1.1-2.5-rl.6—. 71.11.32.5— 9A2.24.51.8-.6-1.0-1.06.—.54.7-3.16.810.33.16.04.71.-1.54.83.62.06.5.94.79.111.17.511.47.73.64.97.49.312.213.99.912.16.626.835.554.257.948.936.946.048.47.873.74.679.72.185.790.394.483.695.699.596.5109.0116.1125.5138.5154.916.112.59.05.75.47.38.911.13.110.812.415.423.834.554.258.550.231.644.348.049.956.366.873.578.574.682.787.593.186.497.496.6106.113.3122.2132.2145.91.4-1.0-1-2.0— 5.1!9.8-.9.31.23.01.0—.6-1.35.31.74.16.91.1.9-2.53.02.81.3-2.82.32.12.'82.83.36.39.135.529.723.122.127.030.633.637.635.436.339.345.658.166.274.80.088.093.7105.5102.0116.0121.0124.8125.0130.7135.1140.2147.2153.6160.1165.8175.5182.5192.7206.3221.838.234.829.623.623.227.829.933.335.835.436.238.444.257.466.874.879.786.995.9101.5100.699.3112.6119.1125.2124.1127.7133.2140.2145.9151.1158.6163.7172.2179.4191.3203. 5219.50.3.1— 4-1.1-.91.81.01.4-.61.1-2.24.0-1.03.42.02.91.91.31.52.13.23.11.2.2.35.634.31.27.525.27.128.331.032.33.234.035.440.350.362.571.876.568.070.275.780.887.0101.2110.8118.8123.5132.6142.3154.2163.4176.2187.199.5213.3226.2244.5262.011.49.26.73.82.93.4.05.66.76.27.58.311.814.08.76.16.515.621.27.728.335.37.539.141.744.249.051.552.353.158.356.858.362.665.768.974.576.Seasonally adjusted annual rates616.8627.7637.9644.2660.8672.9686.5704.4721.2732.3745.3759.1613.3623.5634.4636.8651.4665.3677.8694.0712.3720.0735.4744.73.54.23.67.49.57.68.710.48.912.39.914.4310.7315.6322.4324.3333.8338.8347.5358.8366.0371.6379.6389.3307.1311.4318.8316.9324.3331.2338.8348.4357.0359.3369.7374.93.54.23.67.49.57.68.710.48.912.39.914.4121.9126.1127.8126.4135.1135.2141.0142.6147.6149.6158.1164.0119.6122.4125.0122.0127.7128.8134.3137.9141.8140.6148.7152.12.33.62.84.47.46.46.74.75.89.09.511.9188.8189.6194.6197.9198.7203.6206.5216.2218.4222.0221.4225.3187.5189.0193.8195.0196.6202.4204.4210.5215.2218.7221.0222.81.2.5.82.92.11.22.15.73.13.3.52.4237.3242.7247.1251.1254.3259.8265.1268.8275.5282.1289.9297.068.869.468.568.872.774.373.976.979.878.675.872.9NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.218


TABLE B-5.—Gross national product by major type <strong>of</strong> product, in 1958 prices, 1929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars, 1958 prices]Yearorquarterotalgrossnaional?roduct1929..1930..1931..1932.1933.1934.1935.1936.1937.1938.194019411942194319441945194619471948 ...19491950 —1951195219531954195519561957195819591960 —196119621963196419651966"1964: I IIIII.....IV1965: I IIIII....IV....1966: I IIIII....203.6183.5169.3144.2141.5154.3169.5193.0203.2192.9209.4227.2263.7297.8337.1361.3355.2312.619.9323.7324.1355.3383.395.412.8407.0438.0446.452.5447.3475.9487.7497.2529.8551.580.614.647.'inalsales200.1184.1171.7150.5145.9157.0167.1197.8195.3208.2222.3254.1293.8337.3363.358.302.6310.1319.1328.1347.0372.5391.8411.8409.0431.6441.2451.2448.8471.484.2495.523.8575.4605.6637.Goods output3.5-.6-2.4-6.2-4.3-2.72.43.15.5-2.41.24.99.64.0-2.910.04! 6-3.98.310.93.3.9-2.06.44.81.2-1.54.83.55.84.8.10.TotalTotalgoods Finalsales103.990.583.268.768.877.988.6102.2110.2100.5110.7124.0143.4158.1187.4204.8198.0172.1172.2178.4174.2192.6208.4214.0225.4215.1236.1239.0239.8230.8247.7256. C257.3277.289.7307.328.351.100.491.185.774.973.280.586.299.1104.8102.9109.5119.0133.8154.1187.6206.7201.0162.1172.4173.8178.1184.3197.5210.224.5217.1229.234.2238.5232.242.9252.6255.3271.3283.9302.6319.340.Total3.5-.6-2.4-6.2-4.3-2.72.43.15.5-2.41.24.99.64.0-.2-1.9-2.910.0-.24.6-3.98.310.93.3.9-2.06.44.81.-1.54.83.52.06.05.84.68.810.6Durable goodsFinalsales22.416.38.311.716.921.528.731.021.127.635.650.057.285.695.984.354.760.161.358.073.484.184.691.081.996.596.596.283.694.097.894.9107.0114.2123.1135.5150.930.924.519.213.413.416.720.626.329.123.427.032.843.554.485.297.487.446.158.660.061.068.376.183.89.984.893.093.595.086.491.695.994.9104.111.119.9129.4142.5Total2.7•2.1•3.0•5.1•1.7.2.92.41.9•2.3.62.76.62.9.4-1.5-3.18.61.51.2-3.08.01.51.2-3.03.43.01.2-2.82.42.C2.82.83.26.18.4NondurablegoodsFinalsales70.468.067.060.457.161.067.173.579.279.483.088.493.4100.9101.7108.8113.7117.4112.117.1116.:119.1124.3129.4134.4133.2139.7142.5143.6147.2153.158.2162.3170.3,175.184.193.200.69.566.566.561.559.863.865.672.875.779.582.586.290.399.7102.4109.3113.6116.0113.8113.8117.1116.0121.4127.6134.6132.3136.140.143.6145.9151.2156.7160.3167.2172.5182.7190.3197.90.81.5.5-1.1-2.7-2.81.5.73.6-.1.62.23.11.2-.6-.4.21.4-1.73.3-.93.12.91.8-.2.93.01.8*1.32.51.52.03.13.11.42.2.267.765.861.963.065.368.173.373.974.876.980.089.8107.7131.8144.0144.3113.3106.5109.3112.4117.5130.5136.3140.3141.8147.5153.0160.1163.4171.2176.6184.0193.7200.9211.2221.1232.630.325.320.213.79.811.112.817.519.117.721.823.230.531.917.912.412.927.231.236.137.545.244.444.747.050.254.354.052.653.157.055.055.858.860.461.764.864.210.311.414.819.115.913.518.717.124.618.620.214.518.521.017.522.024.725.431.430.0Seasonally adjusted annual rates569.7578.1585.0587.2600.3607.8618.2631.2640.5643.5649.9657.0566.3574.1581.4579.9591.0600.5609.7621.0632.0631.9640.8643.73.54.03.57.49.37.38.510.28.511.69.113.2300.4305.1311.3311.9319.7322.5330.9341.0344.7346.7352.8359.7296.9301.1307.8304.6310.3315.2322.4330.7336.2335.1343.7346.53.54.03.57.49.37.38.510.28.511.69.113.2119.5123.7125.4123.9131.8131.7138.3140.3145.4146.0153.7158.4117.3120.3122.6119.4124.6125.5131.8135.7139.9137.6145.1147.42.23.52.84.47.26.26.54.75.58.48.711.0180.9181.4185.9188.1187.8190.8192.6200.6199.4200.8199.0201.3179.6180.8185.1185.2185.7189.6190.6195.1196.3197.6198.6199.11.2.5.82.92.11.12.05.63.03.2.42.3206.7210.4212.8214.6216.6220.3223.3224.0227.7230.9234.4237.362.662.660.860.664.065.064.066.268.066.062.860.026.026.226.722.932.230.631.930.732.229.128.530.1NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.219


TABLE B-6.—Gross national product: Receipts and expenditures by major economic groups.1929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year orquarter1929..1930..1931..1932..1933..1934..1935..1936..1937..1938..1939..1940..1941..1942..1943..1944..1945..1946..1947..1948..1949..1950_1951.1952.1953.1954.1955.1956.1957.1958.1959.I960..1961._1962..1963..1964..1965..1966 P.1964: I IIIII....IV....1965: I IIIII....IV....1966: I IIIII.—IV »___PersonsDisposable personalincomeTotal83.374.564.048.745.552.458.566.371.265.570.375.792.7116.9133.5146.3150.2160.0169.8189.1188.6206.9226.6238.3252.6257.4275.3293.2308.5318.8337.3350.0364.4385.3404.6436.6469.1505.3Less:Interestpaidandtransferpaymentsto foreigners1.91.2.9.7.71.01.1.8.8.81.01.41.82.22.42.93.13.54.34.65.15.96.46.57.17.88.18.69.710.711.913.4EqualsTotalexcludinginterestandtransfers81.473.363.148.044.951.757.865.570.364.669.474.791.6116.1132.7145.5149.3158.6168.0186.9186.2204.1223.5234.8248.3252.9270.2287.2302.2312.3330.3342.3356.3376.6394.9425.8457.2491.9PersonalconsumptionexpendituresPersonalsavingordissaving77.260.548.645.851.355.761.966.563.966.870.880.688.599.3108.3119.7143.4160.7173.6176.8191.0206.3216.7230.0236.5254.4266.7281.4290.1311.2325.2335.2355.1375.0401.4431.5465.04.23.42.6.42.13.63.8.72.63.811.027.633.437.329.615.27.313.49.413.117.318.218.316.415.820.620.722.319.117.021.221.619.924.525.726.9GovernmentNet receiptsTaxandnontaxreceiptsor accruals11.310.89.58.99.310.511.412.915.415.015.417.725.032.649.251.253.260.956.858.956.068.784.889.894.389.7100.4109.0115.6114.7128.9139.8144.6157.0168.8174.2189.0212.2Less:Transfers,interest,andsubsidies21.81.93.12.62.73.13.44.13.23.84.24.44.04.44.76.510.418.517.318.821.322.919.919.019.521.923.425.528.733.034.036.541.342.844.446.749.655.7Equals:Netreceipts9.58.96.36.36.77.48.08.812.211.211.213.321.028.244.444.742.832.439.540.134.745.864.970.874.867.876.983.586.881.695.0103.3103.3114.2124.3127.5139.4«156.5ExpendituresTotalexpenditures10.311.112.410.610.712.913.416.115.016.817.618.428.864.093.3103.092.745.542.450.359.160.879.093.7101.296.797.6104.1114.9127.2131.0136.1149.0159.9166.9175.6185.8208.7Less:Transfers,interest,andsubsidiesa1.81.93.12.62.73.13.44.13.23.84.24.44.04.44.76.510.418.517.318.821.322.919.919.019.521.923.425.528.733.034.036.541.342.844.446.749.655.7Equals:Purchases<strong>of</strong>goodsandservices8.59.29.28.18.09.810.012.011.913.013.314.024.859.688.696.582.327.025.131.637.837.959.174.781.674.874.278.686.194.297.099.6107.6117.1122.5128.9136.2153.1Seasonally adjusted annual rates423.4435.1441.2446.6453.2461.0476.2486.1495.1499.9507.8518.210.310.610.911.211.411.812.112.412.713.213.513.9413.1424.5430.3435.4441.8449.2464.1473.7482.4486.7494.3504.3391.1398.0407.5408.8418.9426.8435.0445.2455.6460.1469.9474.422.026.622.826.622.822.429.028.526.726.624.529.9172.3170.8175.4178.3186.5188.5188.6192.6203.1209.5215.946.746.446.746.848.548.151.949.953.453.256.459.7125.6124.4128.7131.5138.0140.5136.7142.6149.7156.3159.5173.1176.5176.2176.2180.1182.4189.6191.1198.4202.2212.5221.646.746.446.746.848.548.151.949.953.453.256.459.7126.5130.1129.5129.4131.6134.3137.7141.2145.0149.0156.2161.9See footnotes at end <strong>of</strong> table.220


TABLE B-6.—Gross national product: Receipts and expenditures by major economic groups,1929-G&—Continued1929.1931.1932.1934 _1935.1937.1938.1940. .1941 __1942. .1943. .1944..1945..1946. .1947..1948. .1949..1950.19511952195319541955.195619571958195919601961.19621963.1964_19651966*.Yearorquarter1964: I—_II—III..IV- _1965: I....II—III-IV..1966: I—II...III..IVx»_Grossretainedearnings111.28.65.33.23.25.26.46.77.78.08.410.511.414.516.317.115.114.520.228.029.729.433.135.136.139.246.347.349.849.456.856.858.766.368.876.983.46 88.274.976.578.477.982.582.483.885.186.587.388.0BusinessGrossprivatedomesticinvestment416.210.35.61.01.43.36.48.511.86.59.313.117.99.85.77.110.630.634.046.035.754.159.351.952.651.767.470.067.860.975.374.871.783.087.193.0106.6116.590.291.892.597.4103.8103.7ioe 7111.9114.5118.5115.0118.0Excess<strong>of</strong> invest--5.1-1.6-.32.21.81.9*-1.8-4.01.6-.9-2.7-6.54.610.610.04.6-16.1-13.8-18.0-6.0-24.7-26.2-16.8-16.5-12.5-21.1-22.8-18.1-11.5-18.5-18.0-13.0-16.8-18.4-16.0-23.1—28.3-15.3-15.3-14.1-19.5-21.3-21.3-22.9-26.8-28.0-31.0-27.0[BiUions <strong>of</strong> dollars]0.4.2.2.2.2.2.2.2.2.2.2.2.2.3.82.92.64.55.64.03.52.52.52.32.52.42.32.42.42.42.62.72.82.82.83.0InternationalNet exports <strong>of</strong> goodsand servicesmentTransferst<strong>of</strong>oreignersby personsandGovernmentExports7.05.43.62.52.43.03.33.54.64.34.45.45.94.84.45.37.214.719.716.815.813.818.718.016.917.819.823.626.523.123.527.228.630.332.337.039.042.9Less:Imports5.94.43.12.12.02.43.13.44.33.03.43.64.64.86.57.17.97.28.210.39.612.015.115.816.615.917.819.620.820.923.323.223.025.126.428.532.038.0Equals:Netexports1.11.0.5.4.4.6.1.1.31.31.11.71.3-2.0-1.8-.67.511.56.46.11.83.72.2.41.82.04.05.72.2.14.05.65.15.98.57.04.9Excess<strong>of</strong>transfersor<strong>of</strong> netex--0.8-.7-.2-.2-.2-.4.1.1—. 1-1.1-.9-1.5-1.1.22.22.11.4-4.6-8.9-1.9-.52.2-.2.32.1.5.5-1.5-3.4.22.3-1.7-3.0-2.5-3.1-5.7-4.2—1.9Seasonally adjusted annual rates2.82.92.82.72.63.12.82.53.42.93.12.736.436.037.238.135.140.540.140.341.741.943.444.627.428.128.829.628.732.333.034.235.637.339.239.89.07.98.48.66.48.27.16.16.04.74.24.8-6.3-5.0-5.7-5.9-3.8-5.1-4.2-3.5-2.6-1.8-1.1—2.1102.491.275.157.755.064.572.581.390.584.189.298.7124.1159.0193.6207.6208.0208.4230.4259.5256.2283.3325.1343.3361,6362.1395.9420.4441.1445.8484.5504.8520.8559.8590.8633.1682.86 739.7616.4628.3640.2647.5664.9675.0687.3704.0722.0733.2744.9Totalincomeor receiptsStatisticaldiscrepancy0.7-.8.7.3.6.5-.21.2.61.31.0.4-1.1-2.02.53.9.1.9-2.0.31.53.32.23.02.72.1-1.11.6-.8-1.0-.8.5-.3-1.4-1.66—20.4-.6-2.3-3.3-4.1-2.1-.8.4-.8-.9Grossnationalproductor expenditure103.190.475.858.055.665.172.282.590.484.790.599.7124. 5157.9191.fi210.1211.9208.5231.3257.6256.5284.8328.4345.5364.6364.8398.0419.2441.1447.3483.7503.7520.1560.3590.5631.7681.2739.5.4616.8627.7637.9644.2660.8672.9686.5704.4721.2732.3745.3759.11 Personal income less personal tax and nontax payments (fines, penalties, etc.).3 Government transfer payments to persons, foreign net transfers by Government, net interest paid bygovernment, and subsidies less current surplus <strong>of</strong> government enterprises.8 Undistributed corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its, corporate inventory valuation adjustment, capital consumption allowances,and wage accruals less disbursements.4 Private business investment, purchases <strong>of</strong> capital goods by private nonpr<strong>of</strong>it institutions, and residentialhousing. See Table B-10.5 Net foreign investment with sign changed.8 Data for corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its are approximations for <strong>the</strong> year as a whole; data for fourth quarter are notavailable. All o<strong>the</strong>r data incorporating or derived from <strong>the</strong>se figures are correspondingly approximateNOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.240-782 0—67- -15221


TABLE B-7.—Gross national product by sector, 1929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year orquarterTotalgrossnationalproductTotalTotalGross private product *BusinessNonfarm 2 FarmHouseholdsRest <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> worldGrossgovernmentproduct 31929..103.198.895.185.49.72.90.84.31930..1931..1932..1933_.1934..1935..1936..1937..1938..1939..90.475.858.055.665.172.282.590.484.790.585.871.253.650.959.566.375.283.577.082.982.468.351.348.957.464.172.981.074.580.374.862.046.844.352.757.166.572.767.974.07.76.34.54.64.77.06.48.36.66.32.72.31.91.71.81.92.02.32.22.3.7.5.4.3.3.4.3.3.4.34.54.74.44.75.65.97.36.97.67.61940..1941..1942..1943..1944..1945..1946..1947..1948..1949..99.7124.5157.9191.6210.1211.9208.5231.3257.6256.591.9115.1142.8166.0177.9176.8187.7214.6240.1237.089.1112.2139.5162.4173.8172.3182.7208.6233.5230.182.6103.3126.5147.2158.5156.4163.9188.5210.2211.46.58.913.015.315.315.918.820.223.318.82.42.52.93.23.74.14.55.15.65.9.4.4.4.4.4.4.6.81.01.07.89.415.125.632.235.220.816.717.419.41950..1951_.1952..1953..1954..1955..1956..1957..1958..1959..I960..1961_.1962..1963..1964..1965..1966'284.8328.4345.5364.6364.8398.0419.2441.1447.3483.7503.7520.1560.3590.5631.7681.2739.5263.9301.0314.3332.7332.4363.8382.6402.0405.2439.4456.3469.2505.7532.4568.7613.4663.3256.3292.8305.8323.6322.7352.9370.8389.3391.7425.0440.7452.3487.4513.0547.4590.8639.3236.3269.9283.7303.3303.1334.1352.2370.9370.9405.3420.2431.4466.2491.5527.0567.1614.520.022.922.220.319.618.818.618.420.819.620/520.921.221.520.423.824.86.46.97.27.88.19.19.810.511.412.213.214.015.016.017.318.319.51.21.31.31.31.61.82.12.22.02.22.42.93.33.44.04.34.520.927.431.231.932.534.236.639.142.144.347.550.954.758.163.067.876.2Seasonally adjusted annual rates1964:1965:IIIIV.".";IIITV'".I616.8627.7637.9644.2660.8672.9686.5704.4555.5565.5574.2579.4595.2606.4618.2633.8534.6544.1552.6558.2573.0583.6595.3611.2513.8523.4532.5538.0551.6559.4570.6586.620.720.720.120.221.424.224.724.716.717.317.617.417.518.018.719.14.24.04.03.84.74.84.13.461.362.363.764.865.666.668.370.61966:jII..III.IV P721.2732.3745.3759.1648.4657.6667.7679.3624.9634.0643.5654.8599.3609.0619.1630.525.725.024.424.319.119.119.720.04.44.44.64.572.874.777.679.91 Gross national product less compensation <strong>of</strong> general government employees.2 Includes compensation <strong>of</strong> employees in government enterprises. Government enterprises are thoseagencies <strong>of</strong> government whose operating costs are at least to a substantial extent covered by <strong>the</strong> sale <strong>of</strong> goodsand services, in contrast to <strong>the</strong> general activities <strong>of</strong> government which are financedmainly by tax revenuesand debt creation. Government enterprises, in o<strong>the</strong>r words, conduct operations essentially commercial incharacter, even though <strong>the</strong>y perform <strong>the</strong>m under governmental auspices. The Post Office and public powersystems are typical examples <strong>of</strong> government enterprises. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, State universities and publicparks, where <strong>the</strong> fees and admissions cover only a nominal part <strong>of</strong> operating costs, are part <strong>of</strong> generalgovernment activities.3 Compensation <strong>of</strong> general government employees.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.222


TABLE B-S.—Gross national product by sector, in 1958 prices, 1929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars, 1958 prices]Year orquarterTotalgrossnationalproductTotalGross private product ]BusinessTotal Nonfarm 2 FarmHouseholdsRest <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> worldGrossgovernmentproduct 31929.203.6190.9182.1165.117.07.41.412.71930.1931.1932.1933.1934.1935.1936.1937.19381939183.5169.3144.2141.5154.3169.5193.0203.2192.9209.4170.1155.8131.0127.5138.3152.4173.1184.3172.6188.7161.4147.7123.8120.6131.1144.9165.4176.4164.6180.7145.4129.21C5.8103.0116.6128.4150.5158.5146.8162.516.118.518.017.514.616.514.917.917.818.27.16.66.05.76.26.46.87.16.87.11.61.41.31.21.01.11.0.81.113.313.513.214.016.017.119.918.920.420.61940194119421943194419451946194719481949227.2263.7297.8337.1361.3355.2312.6309.9323.7324.1205.6236.6257.3272.8286.9282.5275.1281.4295.0294.1197.1228.1248.7264.9278.9274.6267.0272.8286.0284.7179.6209.3228.0245.3259.5256.5248.6255.8267.0266.217.518.820.619.619.418.118.517.019.018.47.67.57.87.27.17.17.17.57.98.21.01.11.21.221.627.240.564.374.472.837.528.628.730.11950195119521953195419551956195719581959355.3383.4395.1412.8407.0438.0446.1452.5447.3475.9324.2344.6353.2371.1366.2397.2404.8410.5405.2433.4314.2334.5343.2360.7355.4385.4392.2397.5391.7419.4294.9316.2324.2340.7335.0364.4371.4377.2370.9398.319.418.419.020.020.420.920.820.320.821.18.78.88.89.19.210.110.610.911.411.71.31.21.21.31.61.82.02.12.02.231.138.841.841.740.940.741.341.942.142.51960196119621963196419651966487.7497.2529.8551.0580.0614.4647.7444.0452.3482.9503.2530.8563.5593.5429.5436.9466.7486.6513.3545.4574.8407.6414.8444.6463.8491.2521.7552.221.922.222.122.822.023.822.612.212.412.913.213.614.014.42.32.93.43.43.94.14.443.744.846.947.849.250.954.2Seasonally adjusted annual rates1964: IIIIIIV569.7578.1585.0587.2521.3529.1535.4537.4503.9511.5517.6520.0482.2488.8495.8497.921.722.621.822.013.213.713.913.74.14.03.93.748.549.049.549.81965: I—.IIIIIIV600.3607.8618.2631.2550.2557.3567.2579.4532.2538.9548.9561.6509.4515.1524.6537.522.823.824.324.113.413.714.214.54.64.64.03.350.150.551.151.81966: I—.II—III640.5643.5649.9657.0588.0589.9595.1601.2569.4571.4576.2582.2546.4548.4554.5559.423.022.921.722.814.314.214.514.64.34.34.44.352.553.654.855.81 Gross national product less compensation <strong>of</strong> general government employees.2 Includes compensation <strong>of</strong> employees in government enterprises. Government enterprises are thoseagencies <strong>of</strong> government whose operating costs are at least to a substantial extent covered by <strong>the</strong> sale <strong>of</strong> goodsand services, in contrast to <strong>the</strong> general activities <strong>of</strong> government which are financed mainly by tax revenuesand debt creation. Government enterprises, in o<strong>the</strong>r words, conduct operations essentially commercialin character, even though <strong>the</strong>y perform <strong>the</strong>m under governmental auspices. The Post Office and publicpower systems are typical examples <strong>of</strong> government enterprises. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, State universities andpublic parks, where <strong>the</strong> fees and admissions cover only a nominal part <strong>of</strong> operating costs, are part <strong>of</strong> generalgovernment activities.3 Compensation <strong>of</strong> general government employees.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.223


TABLE B-9.—Personal consumption expenditures, 1929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Yearorquarter192919301931193219331934....1935....1936193719381939194019411942....19431944194519461947194819491950.—1951....1952.—1953....1954.—1955..__1956....195719581959I960.-.1961.—19621963196419651966 v1964:1 II...III..IV..1965:1.---II-.-III-IV .1966: I—II-.-III-IV v.•3*277.269.960.548.645.851.355.761.966.563.966.870.880.688.599.3108.3119.7143.4160.7173.6176.8191.0206.3216.7230.0236.5254.4266.7281.4290.1311.2325.2335.2355.1375.0401.4431.5465.0Durable goods9.27.25.53.63.54.25.16.36.95.76.77.86.78.015.820.422.724.630.529.629.333.232.839.638.940.837.944.345.344.249.553.959.466.169.43.22.21.6.91.11.41.92.32.41.62.22.73.4.7.8.81.04.06.27.59.913.111.611.114.213.618.416.418.315.419.520.118.422.024.325.829.830.04.83.93.12.11.92.22.63.23.63.13.53.94.94.73.93.84.68.610.911.911.614.114.414.314.915.016.617.517.317.118.918.919.320.522.225.127.130.1Nondurable goods37.734.029.022.722.326.729.332.935.234.035.137.042.950.858.664.371.982.490.596.294.598.1108.8114.0116.8118.3123.3129.3135.6140.2146.6151.3155.9162.6168.6178.9190.6206.119.518.014.711.410.912.213.615.316.515.615.716.619.223.327.429.933.239.043.746.344.846.052.154.755.556.558.160.463.966.668.470.172.174.476.580.485.491.39.48.06.95.14.65.76.06.66.86.87.17.48.811.013.414.416.518.218.820.119.319.621.221.922.122.123.124.124.324.726.427.327.929.630.633. 635.940.01.81.71.51.51.51.61.71.92.12.12.22.32.62.11.31.61.83.03.64.45.05.46.16.87.78.29.09.810.611.011.612.312.412.913.514.115.116.07.06.35.74.85.37.27.99.19.89.510.110.712.214.416.518.420.522.124.425.425.427.129.330.531.631.533.134.936.737.940.241.643.545.748.050.854.1Services30.328.726.022.220.120.421.322.824.424.325.026.028.130.834.237.239.845.349.854.757.662.467.973.479.985.491.498.5105.0112.0120.3128.7135.1143.0152.4163.1174.81.511.511.010.39.07.97.67.78.08.58.99.19.410.211.011.512.012.513.915.717.519.321.323.926.529.331.733.736.038.541.143.746.348.752.055.459.263.267.74.03.93.53.02.83.03.23.43.73.63.84.04.34.85.25.96.46.87.58.18.59.510.411.112.012.614.015.216.217.318.520.020.822.023.124.325.627.22.62.21.91.61.51.61.71.92.01.92.02.12.42.73.43.74.05.05.35.85.96.26.77.17.87.98.28.69.09.310.110.810.611.011.411.812.814.0Seasonally adjusted annual rates391.1398.0407.5408.8418.9426.8435.0445.2455.6460.1469.9474.457.659.861.158.965.164.466.768.070.367.170.270.125.326.027.124.630.129.230.229.931.428.530.130.024.125.425.325.726.026.227.328.829.629.230.731.08.28.48.78.59.09.09.29.39.39.39.49.2174. 9176.5181.7182.4184.5189.4191.4197.0201.9205.6208.1208.778.579.781.481.882.784.885.788.589.991.291.892.332.832.734.334.434.635.636.037.539.439.741.139.913.913.914.214.414.415.215.315.715.816.116.116.149.650.151.851.752.853.854.455.356.758.659.260.4158.7161.6164.7167.5169.3173.0176.9180. 2183. 4187.4191.5195.657.758.759.660.761.662.763.664.766.067.168.269.523.824.224.724.724.725.426.026.326.527.127.627.811.711.711.912.112.212.713.013.413.513.914.214.51 Quarterly data are estimates by Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers.2 Includes standard clothing issued to military personnel.3 Includes imputed rental value <strong>of</strong> owner-occupied dwellings.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s (except as noted).224


TABLE B-10.—Gross private domestic investment, 1929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year orquarterprivatedomesticinvestmentTotalFixed investmentTotalNonresidentialTotalStructuresTotalNonfarmProducers'durableequipmentTotalNonfarmResidential structuresTotalNonfarmFarm Change inbusinessinventoriesTotalNonfarm1929-1930..1931-1932..1933-1934..1935-1936-1937-1938-1939-1940-1941-1942..1943-1944..1945-1946-1947-1948-1949-1950-1951-1952_.1953-1954-1955..1956-1957-1958..1959..I960-1961-1962..1963..1964...1965...1966 P.1964: I II—III...IV...1965: I II—III...IV...1966: III—IV K".16.210.35.61.01.43.36.48.511.86.59.313.117.99.85.77.110.630.634.046.035.754.159.351.952.651.767.470.067.860.975.374.871.783.087.193.0106.6116.590.291.892.597.4103.8103.7106.7111.9114. 5118.5115. 0118.014.510.66.83.43.04.15.37.29.27.48.911.013.48.16.48.111.624.234.441.338.847.349.048.852.153.361.465.366.562.470.571.369.777.081.388.397.5105.110.68.35.02.72.43.24.15.67.35.45.97.59.56.05.06.810.117.023.426.925.127.931.831.634.233.638.143.746.441.645.148.447.051.754.360.769.779.35.04.02.31.2.91.01.21.62.41.92.02.32.91.91.31.82.86.87.58.88.59.211.211.412.713.114.317.218.016.616.718.118.419.219.521.024.927.94.83.92.31.2.91.01.21.62.41.81.92.22.81.81.21.72.76.16.78.07.78.510.410.511.912.313.616.517.215.815.917.417.718.518.820.324.227.35.64.32.71.51.52.22.94.04.93.54.05.36.64.13.75.07.310.215.918.116.618.720.720.221.520.623.826.528.425.028.430.328.632.534.839.744.851.44.93.72.41.31.31.82.43.34.12.93.44.65.63.53.24.26.39.214.015.513.715.717.717.618.618.021.224.225.922.025.427.725.829.431.235.940.646.24.02.31.7.71.21.61.92.02.93.43.92.11.41.31.57.211.114.413.719.417.217.218.019.723.321.620.220.825.522.822.625.327.027.627.825.83.82.21.6.7.5.81.11.51.81.92.83.23.71.91.21.11.46.710.413.612.818.616.416.417.219.022.720.919.520.124.822.222.024.826.427.027.225.30.2 1.7-.4-1.1-2.5-1.6-.71.11.32.5-.9.42.24.51.8-.6-1.0-1.06.4-.54.7-3.16.810.33.1.4-1.56.04.71.3-1.54.83.62.06.05.94.79.111.4Seasonally adjusted annual rates86.687.688.990.094.496.098.0101.5105.6106.2105.1103.658.159.761.763.366.767.970.273.977.078.280.381.720.320.921.021.823.624.624.426.828.527.927.727.619.620.220.321.222.924.023.826.127.827.227.027.037.938.840.741.443.143.345.847.148.550.352.654.134.035.236.937.739.339.441.342.343.745.447.548.228.527.927.226.727.728.127.827.628.628.024.821.927.927.326.626.227.227.527.327.028.027.424.321.30.6.6.6.6.6.6.5.5.5.6.6.63.54.23.67.49.57.68.710.48.912.39.914.41.8-.1-1.6-2.6-1.4.2.42.11.7-1.0.31.94.0.7-.6-.6-.66.41.33.0-2.26.09.12.11.1-2.15.55.1.8-2.34.83.31.75.35.15.38.111.73.65.14.67.99.46.77.29.08.512.110.415.6NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.225


Year orquarterTotalnationalincome1TABLE B-l 1.—National income by type <strong>of</strong> income, 1929-66Compensation <strong>of</strong>employeesTotalWagesandsalariesSupplementstowagesTotalandsala-[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Business and pr<strong>of</strong>essionalincomeand inventoryvaluationadjustmentIncome<strong>of</strong>unincorporatedenterprisesInventoryvaluationadjustmentIncome<strong>of</strong>farmproprietors3Rentalincome<strong>of</strong>personsTotalCorporate pr<strong>of</strong>itsand inventoryvaluationadjustmentCorporatepr<strong>of</strong>itsbeforetaxes 4InventoryvaluationadjustmentNetinterest1929...1930...1931...1932...1933...1934...1935...1936...1937...1938...1939...1940...1941...1942...1943...1944...1945...1946...1947...1948._.1949...1950...1951...1952...1953...1954...1955...1956...1957...1958...1959...1960...1961...1962...1963-..1964.-.1965.-.1966 »..1964: III....III...IV...1965: III....III...IV...1966: III....III...IV.86.875.459.742.840.349.557.265.073.667.472.681.1104.2137.1170.3182.6181.5181.9199.0224.2217.5241.1278.0291.4304.7303.1331.0350.8366.1367.8400.0414.5427.3457.7481.9517.3559.0«609.7504.0513.7522.9528.5543.3552.2562.7577.8595.7604.1613.851.146.839.831.129.534.337.342.947.945.048.152.164.885.3109.5121.2123.1117.9128.9141.1141.0154.6180.7195.3209.1208.0224.5243.1256.0257.8279.1294.2302.6323.6341.0365.7392.9433.3355.3362.2369.8375.3381.7387.8395.6406.5419.6427.9438.3447.550.446.239.130.529.033.736.741.946.143.045.949.862.182.1105.8116.7117.5112.0123.0135.4134.5146.8171.1185.1198.3196.5211.3227.8238.7239.9258.2270.8278.1296.1311.1333.6358.4392.3324.4330.6337.4342.2348.2353.7360.8370.8380.0387.4396.7405.00.7.7.5.6.61.01.82.02.22.32.73.23.84.55.65.95.95.86.57.89.610.210.911.513.215.217.317.920.923.424.627.529.932.034.541.031.031.732.433.133.534.134.835.739.640.541.542.59.07.65 83.63.34.75.56.77.26.97.48.611.114.017.018.219.221.620.322.722.624.026.127.127.527.630.331.332.833.235.134.235.637.137.939.940.741.88.86.85.13.33.94.85.56.87.26.77.611.714.417.118.319.323.321.823.122.225.126.526.927.627.630.531.833.133.235.334.335.637.137.939.941.042.20.1-.1*.2-.2-.4-.2-.1-.1-1.7-1.5-.4.5-1.1-.3.2-.2_ o-'.5-.3-.1-.1-.4-.46.24.33.42.12.63.05.34.36.04.44.44.56.49.811.711.612.214.915.217.512.713.515.815.013.012.411.411.411.313.411.412.012.813.013.112.015.116.0Seasonally adjusted annual rates39.139.940.340.340.540.440.741.141.441.641.942.239.140.240.340.240.640.941.041.742.042.242.442.2-0.2-.1.1-.2-.5-.3-.6-.6-.6-.5*12.212.211.711.912.915.516.016.017. G16.315.415.25.44.83.82.72.01.71.71.82.12.62.72.93.54.55.15.45.66.67.18.08.49.410.311.512.713.613.914.314.815.415.615.816.016.717.117.718.318.917.417.617.817.918.118.318.418.518.718.818.919.110.57.02.0-1.3-1.21.73.45.66.84.96.39.815.220.324.423.819.219.325.633.030.837.742.739.939.638.046.946.145.641.151.749.950.355.758.966.674.279.865.366.567.866.873.272.774.076.980.079.979.110.03.7-.4-2.31.02.33.66.36.84.07.010.017.721.525.124.119.724.631.535.228.942.643.938.940.638.348.648.847.241.452.149.750.355.459.467.075.781.865.866.867.867.774.574.575.078.782.782.881.90.53.32.41.0-2.1-.6-.2-.71.0-.7-.2-2.5-1.2-.8-.3-.6-5.3-5.9-2.21.9-5.0-1.21.0-1.0-.3-1.7-2.7-1.5-.3-.5.2-.1.3-.4-1.5-2.04.74.95.04.64.14.14.13.83.73.63.53.33.23.12.72.32.21.51.91.81.92.02.32.62.83.64.14.65.66.87.18.410.011.613.815.517.820.0.5-0.5-.3*-.9-1.3-1.8-1.0-1.8-2.8-2.9-2.814.715.115.716.316.917.518.118.719.119.620.221.01 National income is <strong>the</strong> total net income earned in production. It differs from gross national productmainly in that it excludes depreciation charges and o<strong>the</strong>r allowances for business and institutional consumption<strong>of</strong> durable capital goods, and indirect business taxes. See Table B-12.2 Employer contributions for social insurance and to private pension, health, and welfare funds; compensationfor injuries; directors' fees; pay <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> military reserve; and a few o<strong>the</strong>r minor items.3 Excludes income resulting from net reductions <strong>of</strong> farm inventories and gives credit in computing incometo net additions to farm inventories during <strong>the</strong> period.4 See Table B-66 for corporate tax liability and pr<strong>of</strong>its after taxes.5 Data for corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its are approximations for <strong>the</strong> year as a whole; data for fourth quarter are notavailable. All o<strong>the</strong>r data incorporating or derived from <strong>the</strong>se figures are correspondingly approximate.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.226


TABLE B-12.—Relation <strong>of</strong> gross national product and national income, 1929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year or quarterGrossnationalproductLess:CapitalconsumptionallowancesEquals:NetnaproductLess:Indirect business taxesTotalStateandlocalPlus:Subsidieslesscurrentsurplus<strong>of</strong> governmententerprisesFederalBusinesstransferpaymentsStatisticaldiscrepancyEquals:Nationalincome1929103.1 7.9 95.2 -0.1 7.0 1.2 5.8 0.6 0.7 86.8193090.4 8.0 82.4 -.1 7.2 1.0 6.1 .5 -.8 75.4193175.8 7.9 68.0 * 6.9 .9 6.0 .6 .7 59.7193258.0 7.4 50.7 * 6.8 .9 5.8 .7 .3 42.8193355.6 7.0 48.6 * 7.1 1.6 5.4 .7 .6 40.3193465.1 6.8 58.2 .3 7.8 2.2 5.6 .6 .5 49.5193572.2 6.9 65.4 .4 8.2 2.2 6.0 .6 -.2 57.2193682.5 7.0 75.4 * 8.7 2.3 6.4 .6 1.2 65.0193790.4 7.2 83.3 .1 9.2 2.4 6.8 .6 * 73.6193884.7 7.3 77.4 .2 9.2 2.2 6.9 .4 .6 67.4193990.5 7.3 83.2 .5 9.4 2.3 7.0 .5 1.3 72.6194099.7 7.5 92.2 .4 10.0 2.6 7.4 .4 1.0 81.11941124.5 8.2 116.3 .1 11.3 3.6 7.7 .5 .4 104.21942157.9 9.8 148.1 .2 11.8 4.0 7.7 .5 -1.1 137.11943191.6 10.2 181.3 .2 12.7 4.9 7.8 .5 -2.0 170.31944210.1 11.0 199.1 .7 14.1 6.2 8.0 .5 2.5 182.61945211.9 11.3 200.7 .8 15.5 7.1 8.4 .5 3.9 181.51946208.5 9.9 198.6 .9 17.1 7.8 9.3 .5 .1 181.91947231.3 12.2 219.1 -.2 18.4 7.8 10.6 .6 .9 199.01948257.6 14.5 243.1 -.1 20.1 8.0 12.1 .7 -2.0 224.2i1949256.5 16.6 239.921.3 8.0 13.3 .8 .3 217.51950284.8 18.3 266.4 .2 23.3 8.9 14.5 .8 1.5 241.11951328.4 21.2 307.2 .2 25.2 9.4 15.8 .9 3.3 278.01952345.5 23.2 322.3 -.1 27.6 10.3 17.3 1.0 2.2 291.41953364.6 25.7 338.9 -.4 29.6 10.9 18.7 1.2 3.0 304.71954364.8 28.2 336.6 -.2 29.4 9.7 19.7 L.I 2.7 303.11955398.0 31.5 366.5 -.1 32.1 10.7 21.4 L.2 2.1 331.01956419.2 34.1 385.2 .8 34.9 11.2 23.6 L.4 -1.1 350.81957441.1 37.1 404.0 .9 37.3 11.8 25.5 L.5 * 366.11958447.3 38.9 408.4 .9 38.5 11.5 27.0 L.6 1.6 367.81959483.7 41.4 442.3 .1 41.5 12.5 28.9 L.7 -.8 400.01960503.7 43.4 460.3 .2 45.2 13.5 31.7 1.9 -1.0 414.51961520.1 45.2 474.9 1.4 47.7 13.6 34.1 2.0 -.8 427.31962560.3 50.0 510.4 1.4 51.5 14.6 36.9 2.1 .5 457.71963590.5 52.6 537.9 .8 54.7 15.3 39.4 2.3 -.3 481.91964631.7 56.0 575.7 1.3 58.5 16.2 42.3 2.5 -1.4 517.31965681.2 59.6 621.6 1.0 62.7 16.8 45.8 2.6 -1.6 559.01966739.5 63.1 676.4 1.3l _ # 265.5 16.0 49.5 51.61609.7Seasonally adjusted annual rates1964: I_616.8 54.6 562.2 1.0 56.4 15.5 40.8 2.4 0.4 504.0II627.7 55.5 572.2 1.3 57.9 16.1 41.9 2.5 -.6 513.7III_-_ 637.9 56.6 581.4 1.4 59.5 16.6 42.9 2.6 -2.3 522.9IV644.2 57.5 586.6 1.4 60.2 16.5 43.7 2.6 -3.3 528.51965: I660.8 58.2 602.7 1.2 62.0 17.5 44.6 2.6 -4.1 543.3II672.9 59.1 613.8 1.0 62.2 16.8 45.4 2.5 -2.1 552.2III___. 686.5 60.2 626.3 .9 62.7 16.3 46.4 2.5 -.8 562.7IV____ 704.4 60.8 643.6 .9 63.6 16.7 47.0 2.6 .4 577.81966: I721.2 61.6 659.7 .8 63.0 15.2 47.8 2.6 -.8 595.7II732.3III____IV P— 759.1745.362.764.663.7 681.6669.6 .9 64.71.5694.666.316.11.8 68.116.248.716.5 51.650.02.6 -.9 604.12.6 .4 613.82.6\1 Data for corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its are approximations for <strong>the</strong> year as a whole; data for fourth quarter are notavailable. All o<strong>the</strong>r data incorporating or derived from <strong>the</strong>se figures are correspondingly approximate.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.227


TABLE B-13.—Relation <strong>of</strong> national income and personal income, 1929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Less:Plus:Equals:Year or quarterNationalincomeCorporatepr<strong>of</strong>itsand inventoryvaluationadjustmentContributionsforsocialinsuranceWageaccrualslessdisbursementsGovernmenttransferpaymentsto personsInterestpaidbygovernment(net)and byconsumersDividendsBusinesstransferpaymentsPersonalincome1929 -193019311932193319341935193619371938193986.875.459.742.840.349.557.265.073.667.472.610.57.02.0-1.3-1.21.73.45.66.84.96.30.2.3.3.3.3.3.3.61.82.02.1****** **0.91.02.11.41.51.61.82.91.92.42.52.51.81.81.71.61.71.71.71.91.91.95.85.54.12 52.02.62 84.5• 4.73.23.80.6.5.67.7.6.6.6.6.4.585.977.065.950 247.054.060 468.674.168 372.8194019411942194319441945194619471948 .194919501951 -. -.195219531954 __19551956195719581959I960 .1961196219631964 -__19651966 P81.1104.2137.1170.3182.6181.5181.9199.0224.2217.5241.1278.0291.4304.7303.1331.0350.8366.1367.8400.0414.5427.3457.7481.9517.3559.01609.79.815.220.324.423.819.219.325.633.030.837.742.739.939.638.046.946.145.641.151.749.950.355.758.966.674.22.32.83.54.55.26.16.05.75.25.76.98.28.78.89.811.112.614.514.817.620.721.424.026.928.029.237.80 2-.2****.1*-.1 ********2.72.62.62.53.15.610.811.110.511.614.311.512.012.814.916.117.119.924.124.926.630.431.233.034.237.141.92.12.22.22.63.34.25.25.56.16.57.27.68.19.09.510.111.212.012.113.615.115.016.117.619.120.622.84.04.44.34.44.64.65.66.37.07.28.88.68.68.99.310.511.311.711.612.613.413.815.216.517.319.220.9.4.5.5.5.5.5.5.6.7.8.8.91.01.21L.456]71.92.02.12.32.52.62.678.396.0122.9151.3165.3171.1178.7191.3210.2207.2227.6255.6272.5288.2290.1310.9333.0351.1361.2383.5401.0416.8442.6465.5496.0535.1580.4Seasonally adjusted annual rates1964: I IIIIIIV504.0513.7522.9528.565.366.567.866.827.427.728.228.60.1-.134.633.934.134.418.618.919.419.617.117.317.417.72.42.52.62.6484.0492.0500.3507.51965' I II -.- .IIIIV543.3552.2562.7577.873.272.774.076.928.829.029.229.8*36.035.239.437.920.020.520.921.018.118.819.520.22.62.52.52.6518.0527.6541.9552.81966: I IIIIIIV p595.7604.1613.880.079.979.136.537.038.539.3**40.040.142.345.321.922.523.023.820.921.121.120.72.62.62.62.6564.6573.5585.2598.11 Data for corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its are approximations for <strong>the</strong> year as a whole; data for fourth quarter are notavailable. All o<strong>the</strong>r data incorporating or derived from <strong>the</strong>se figures are correspondingly approximate.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.228


TABLE B-14.—Disposition <strong>of</strong> personal income, 7920-66Year orquarter1929 _1930.1931.1932.1933.1934.1935.1936..1937.1938.1940..1941..1942..1943..1944..1945..1946..1947-1948..1949..1950.1951.1952.1953.1954.1955.1956.1957.1958.1959.1960...1961.-.1962 ...1963..._19641965....1966 P1964:IIIII-IV..1965: I_.II,IIIIV..1966: I...II—IIIIV P.PersonalincomeLess:PersonaltaxandnontaxpaymentsEquals:DisposablepersonalincomeLess: Personal outlaysTotaloutlaysPersonalconsumptionexpendituresInterestpaid byconsumersPersonaltransferpaymentsto foreignersEquals:PersonalsavingBillions <strong>of</strong> dollars85.977.065.950.247.054.060.468.674.168.372.878.396.0122.9151.3165.3171.1178.7191.3210.2207.2227.6255.6272.5288.2290.1310.9333.0351.1361.2383.5401.0416.8442.6465.5496.0535.1580.42.62.51.91.51.51.61.92.32.92.92.42.63.36.017.818.920.918.721.421.118.620.729.034.135.632.735.539.842.642.346.250.952.457.460.959.466.075.183.374.564.048.745.552.458.566.371.265.570.375.792.7116.9133.5146.3150.2160.0169.8189.1188.6206.9226.6238.3252.6257.4275.3293.2308.5318.8337.3350.0364.4385.3404.6436.6469.1505.379.171.161.449.346.552.056.462.767.464.867.771.881.789.3100.1109.1120.7144.8162.5175.8179.2193.9209.3220.2234.3241.0259.5272.6287.8296.6318.3333.0343.3363.7384.7412.1443.4478.477.269.960.548.645.851.355.761.966.563.966.870.880.688.599.3108.3119.7143.4160.7173.6176.8191.0206.3216.7230.0236 5254.4266.7281.4290.1311.2325.2335.2355.1375.0401.4431.5465.01.5.9.7.5.5.5.5.6.7.7.7.8.9.7.5.5.5.81.11.51.92.42.73.03.84.04.75.45.85.96.57.37.68.19.110.111.312.70.3.3.3.2.2.2.2.22.2.2.2.2.1.2.4.5.7.7.7.5.5.4.4.5.5.5.6.6.6.6.5.5.5.6.6.6.7Seasonally adjusted annual rates484.0492.0500.3507.5518.0527.6541.9552.8564.6573.5585.2598.160.756.959.160.964.966.665.766.769.573.677.479.9423.4435.1441.2446.6453.2461.0476.2486.1495.1499.9507.8518.2401.4408.5418.4420.0430.3438.6447.1457.6468.4473.3483.3488.4391.1398.0407.5408.8418.9426.8435.0445.2455.6460.1469.9474.49.710.010.310.610.811.211.511.812.112.512.813.20.6.6.6.6.6.6.6.6.6.7.7.7 4.23.42.6-.6Q!42.13.63.8.72.63.811.027.633.437.329.615.27.313.49.413.117.318.118.316.415.820.620.722.319.117.021.221.619.924.525.726.922.026.622.826.622.822.429.028.526.726.624.529.9Percent <strong>of</strong> disposablepersonal incomePersonaloutlaysTotalConsumptionexpendituresPersonalsavingPercent95.095.495.9101.3102.099.396.394.694.798.996.394.988.276.475.074.580.390.595.792.995.093.799. 492.492.893.694.393.093.393.094.495.194.294.495.194.494.594.794.893.994.894.094.995.193.994.194.694.795.294.292.793.894.499.8100.698.095.293.393.497.695.093.686.975.774.474.079.789.694.691.893.892.391.090.991.191.992.491.091.291.092.392.992.092.292.791.992.092.092.491.592.491.592.492.691.391.692.092.092.591.55.04.64.1-1.3-2.0.73.75.45.31.13.75.111.823.625.025.519.79.54.37.15.06.37.67.67.26.45.77.06.77.05.64.95.85.64.95.65.55.35.26.15.26.05.04.96.15.95.45.34.85.8NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.229


TABLE B-15.—Sources <strong>of</strong> personal income, 1929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year or quarterTotalpersonalincomeWage and salary disbursements iTotalCommodityproducingindustriesTotalManufacturingDistributiveindustriesServiceindustriesGovernmentO<strong>the</strong>rlaborincomelProprietors'incomeBusinessandpr<strong>of</strong>essionalFarm 21929-1930..1931..1932..1933..1934-1935-1936-1937-1938-1939-1940..1941-1942-1943..1944__1945-1946-1947..1948-1949-1950-1951-1952-1953-1954-1955.-1956-1957__1958-1959-.1960-1961-1962—1963-1964-1965-1966 *,1964: I...II..III.IV..1965: I...II..III.IV..1966: I...II..III.IV*85.977.065.950.247.054.060.468.674.168.372.878.396.0122.9151.3165.3171.1178.7191.3210.2207.2227.6255.6272.5288.2290.1310.9333.0351.1361.2383.5401.0416.8442.6465.5496.0535.1580.450.446.239.130.529.033.736.741.946.143.045.949.862.182.1105.6116.9117.5112.0123.0135.3134.6146.7171.0185.1198.3196.5211.3227.8238.7239.9258.2270.8278.1296.1311.1333.6358.4392.321.518.514.39.99.812.113.515.818.415.317.419.727.539.148.950.345.846.054.361.057.764.676.181.889.485.492.8100.2103.899.7109.1112.5112.8120.8125.7134.0144.3158.216.113.810.87.77.89.610.812.414.611.813.615.621.730.940.942.938.236.542.547.244.750.359.464.271.267.673.979.582.578.786.989.789.896.7100.6107.2115.5127.215.614.512.59.88.89.910.711.813.212.613.314.216.318.020.122.724.831.035.237.637.739.944.346.949.850.253.457.760.560.864.868.169.172.576.081.286.793.18.48.07.15.85.25.75.96.57.16.87.17.58.19.09.910.912.014.416.117.918.619.921.723.325.126.428.931.633.935.938.741.544.046.849.954.158.163.54.95.25.35.05.16.16.57.97.58.28.28.410.216.026.633.034.920.717.418.920.622.428.933.134.134.636.238.340.443.545.648.752.256.059.564.369.277.40.6.7.7.91.11.51.81.92.32.73.03.84.85.36.06.37.38.49.59.911.312.012.713.914.916.618.520.8Seasonally adjusted annual rates9.07.65.83.63.34.75.56.77.26.97.48.611.114.017.018.219.221.620.322.722.624.026.127.127.527.630.331.332.833.235.134.235.637.137.939.940.741.8484.0492.0500.3507.5518.0527.6541.9552.8564.6573.5585.2598.1324.4330.6337.2342.3348.2353.7360.8370.8380.0387.4396.7405.0130.2132.9135.5137.4140.9142.6144.8148.9153.8157.0159.6162.3104.2106.2108.6109.7112.6114.0116.2119.2123.0126.0128.6131.279.180.581.983.184.686.087.189.190.892.193.995.852.653.754.855.455.757.259.260.561.362.564.465.862.663.565.066.367.068.069.772.374.175.978.881.015.916.416.917.317.818.218.819.420.020.621.121.739.139.940.340.340.540.440.741.141.441.641.942.2See footnotes at end <strong>of</strong> table.230


TABLE B-15.—Sources <strong>of</strong> personal income, 1929-66—Continued[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Transfer paymentsYear orquarterRentalincome<strong>of</strong> personsDividendsPersonalinterestincomeTotalOld-ageand survivorsinsurancebenefitsStateunemploymentinsurancebenefits-Veterans'benefitsO<strong>the</strong>rPersonalcontributionsfor socialinsuranceNonagriculturalpersonalincome 31929..5.45.87.21.50.60.90.177.61930..1931..1932..1933..1934..1935..1936..1937..1938..1939-4.83.82.72.01.71.71.82.12.62.76.54.12.52.02.62.84.54.73.23.86.76.35.75.85.75.55.65.55.51.52.72.22.12.22.43.52.42.83.00.4.4.61.6.8.5.4.51.9.6.5.51.11.41.61.81.91.61.81.92.0.1.2.2.2.2.2.2.670.860.846.743.249.853.963.066.762.666.91940..1941..1942..1943..1944..1945..1946..1947_.1948..1949..2.93.54.55.15.45.66.67.18.08.44.04.44.34.44.64.65.66.37.07.25.45.55.35.35.66.36.87.57.98.53.13.13.13.03.66.211.311.711.212.40.1.1.2.2.3.4.5.6.7.5.1.1.41.1.8.81.7.5.5.5.5.92.86.76.75.85.12.02.22.22.22.42.73.13.74.14.9.7.81.21.82.22.32.02.12.22.272.387.8111.0137.3151.2156.4161.0173.0189.4191.31950_.1951...1952..1953-.1954..1955-1956..1957..1958..1959..9.410.311.512.713.613.914.314.815.415.68.68.68.99.310.511.311.711.612.69.29.910.611.813.114.215.717.618.920.715.112.513.014.016.017.318.521.425.71.01.92.23.03.64.95.77.38.510.21.4.81.01.02.01.41.41.83.92.54.93.93.93.73.94.34.34.44.64.67.95.96.06.36.56.87.27.98.79.42.93.43.84.04.65.25.86.76.97.9210.9236.4254.1271.9274.7296.4318. 5336.6344.3368.519601961. _____19621963196419651966 p15.816.016.717.117.718.318.913.413.815.216.517.319.220.923.425.027.731.434.638.442.828.532.433.335.336.839.744.511.112.614.315.216.018.121.04.02.92.82.62.21.84.64.84.85.05.35.66.110.010.911.212.212.913.815.79.39.610.311.812.513.217.6385.2400.0425.5448.1479.7515.6559.7Seasonally adjusted annual rates1964: I___.II —III..IV..17.417.617.817.917.117.317.417.733.334.035.135.937.136.436.637.015.815.916.116.32.72.62.52.45.25.35.35.313.312.712.813.012.312.412.612.8467.7475.5484.4491.31965: I—.II—III—IV-.18.118.318.418.518.118.819.520.236.938.038.939.738.637.842.040.516.716.620.418.62.42.22.22.05.55.65.75.814.113.313.714.113.113.213.213.5500.9507.7521.5532.21966: I—.II—III-IV v.18.718.818.919.120.921.121.120.741.042.143.244.842.642.844.947.919.519.721.223.52.01.61.81.75.96.06.16.315.215.415.816.416.917.118.118.5542.9552.5565.1578.21 The total <strong>of</strong> wage and salary disbursements and o<strong>the</strong>r labor income differs from compensation <strong>of</strong> employeesin Table B-ll in that it excludes employer contributions for social insurance and excludes <strong>the</strong> excess<strong>of</strong> wage accruals over wage disbursements.2 Excludes income resulting from net reductions <strong>of</strong> inventories and gives credit in computing income tonet additions to inventories during <strong>the</strong> period.3 Nonagricultural income is personal income exclusive <strong>of</strong> net income <strong>of</strong> unincorporated farm enterprises,farm wages, agricultural net interest, and net dividends paid by agricultural corporations.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.231


TABLE B—16.— Total and per capita disposable personal income and personalexpenditures•, in current and 1958 prices, 7929-66consumptionDisposable personal incomePersonal consumption expendituresYear or quarterTotal (billions<strong>of</strong> dollars)Currentprices1958pricesPer capita(dollars)Currentprices1958pricesTotal (billions<strong>of</strong> dollars)Currentprices1958pricesPer capita(dollars)Currentprices1958pricesPopulation(thousands)*1929.83.3150.66831,23677.2139.66341,145121,8751930.1931.1932.1933.1934.1935.1936.1937.1938.1939.74.564.048.745.552.458.566.371.265.570.3139.0133.7115.1112.2120.4131.8148.4153.1143.6155.96055163903624144595185525045371,1281,0779218939521,0351,1581,1871,1051,19060.548.645.851.355.761.966.563.966.8130.4126.1114.8112.8118.1125.5138.4143.1140.2148.25674873893644064374835164925101,0591,0169198979349851,0801,1101,0791,131123,188124,149124. 949125,690126,485127.362128,181128,961129,969131,0281940.1941.1942.1943.1944.1945.1946.1947.1948.1949.75.792.7116.9133.5146.3150.2160.0169.8189.1188.6166.3190.3213.4222.8231.6229.7227.0218.0229.8230.85736958679761,0571,0741,1321,1781,2901,2641,2591,4271,5821,6291,6731,6421,6061,5131, 5671,54770.880.688.599.3108.3119.7143.4160.7173.6176.8155.7165.4161.4165.8171.4183.0203.5206.3210.8216.55366046567267828551,0141.1151,1841,1851,1781,2401,1971,2131,2381,3081,4391,4311,4381,451132.122133, 402134,860136, 739138,397139,928141,389144,126146,631149,1881950.1951 _1952 _1953.1954.1955-1956-1957.1958.1959-206.9226.6238.3252.6257.4275.3293.2308.5318.8337.3249.6255.7263.3275.4278.3296.7309.3315.8318.8333.01,3641,4691,518'. t 583,585,666,743,801,831,9051,6461,6571,6781,7261,7141,7951,8391,8441,8311,881191.0206.3216.7230.0236.5254.4266.7281.4290.1311.2230.5232.8239.4250.8255.7274.2281.4288.2290.1307.31,2591,3371,381, 441,456,539,585,643,666,7581,5201,5091,5251,5721,5751,6591,6731,6831,6661,735151,684154,287156,954159.565162,391165,275168,221171,274174,141177,0731960-1961.1962.1963.1964.1965-1966 i350.0364.4385.3404.6436.6469.1505.3340.2350.7367.3381.3406.5430.8451.5,937,9832,0642,1362,2722,4112,5671,8831,9091,9682,0132,1162,2142,294325.2335.2355.1375.0401.4431.5465.0316.1322.5338.4353.3373.8396.2415.5,800,8241,9021,9802,0892,2182,3621,7491,7551,8131,8651,9462,0362,111180,684183, 756186,656189,417192,120194,572196,842Seasonally adjusted annual rates1964: I—.II...III..IV..1965: I...II...III..IV...1966: I....II...III..IV v.423.4435.1441.2446.6453.2461.0476.2486.1495.1499.9507.8518.2395.7405.5410.8413.9418.8423.7436.8443.9448.4447.9452.2457.02,2152,2692,2922,3122,3392,3732,4432,4862,5252,5432,5762,6212,0702,1142,1342,1422,1622,1812,2412,2702,2872,2782,2942,311391.1398.0407.5408.8418.9426.8435.0445.2455.6460.1469.9474.4365.7371.0379.5378.9387.1392.2398.9406.5412.8412.2418.3418.52,0462,0752,1172,1162,1622,1972,2322,2772,3242,3402,3842,3991,9131,9341,9721,9611,9982,0192,0472,0792,1052,0972,1222,117191,163191,781192,492193,196193,731194, 268194,898195, 543196,082196, 585197,124197,717i Population <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> United States including armed forces abroad. Annual data are for July 1; quarterlydata are for middle <strong>of</strong> period, interpolated from monthly data.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce (Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s and Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Census) and Council<strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers.232


TABLEB-17. —Number and money income <strong>of</strong> families and unrelatedYearNumber(millions)TotalMedianincome (1965prices)Families !individuals, 1947-65Number(millions)Poor 2Incidence(percent)19471948194937.238.639.34,2754,1784,11611.212.012.730.031.232.31950195119521953195439.940.640.841.242.04,3514,5074,6255,0024,88911.911.310.710.111.029.927.826.324.626.21955195619571958195942.943.543.744.245.15,2235,5615,5545,5435,85610.19.49.59.69.323.621.521.721.820.61960196119621963196445.546.347.047.447.85,9916,0546,2206,4446,6769.29.38.98.58.220.320.118.918.017.1196548.36,8828.016.5Number(millions)TotalUnrelated individuals 3Medianincome (1965prices)Number(millions)Poor*Incidence(percent)194719481949 . .1950195119521953195419551956195719581959I960196119621963196419658.28.49.09.49.19.79.59.79.99.810.410.910.911.111.211.011.212.112.11,4071,3651,4301,4211,4701,6921,6621,4541,5611,6701,7201,6751,7181,8571,8621,8411,8622,0172,1104.34.54.74.94.64.54.55.04.84.64.85.15.04.94.94.84.85.04.752.354.051.952.150.746.647.551.248.946.946.146.946.044.343.543.242.841.438.81 The term "family" refers to a group <strong>of</strong> two or more persons related by blood, marriage, or adoption andresiding toge<strong>the</strong>r; all such persons are considered members <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> same family.2 Poverty is defined to include all families with total money income <strong>of</strong> less than $3,000 in 1965 prices;<strong>the</strong>se are also referred to as poor families. Incidence <strong>of</strong> poverty is measured by <strong>the</strong> percent that poor familiesare <strong>of</strong> all families.3 The term "unrelated individuals" refers to persons 14 years <strong>of</strong> age and over (o<strong>the</strong>r than inmates <strong>of</strong> institutions)who are not living with any relatives.4 Poverty is denned to include all unrelated individuals with total money income <strong>of</strong> less than $1,500 in1965 prices. Incidence <strong>of</strong> poverty is measured by <strong>the</strong> percent that poor unrelated individuals are <strong>of</strong> allunrelated individuals.NOTE.—The number <strong>of</strong> poor and incidence <strong>of</strong> poverty shown in this table differ from data shown inChapter 5, Tables 18 and 19. In Chapter 5, poverty is defined by <strong>the</strong> new Social Security Administrationpoverty-income standard; it takes into account family size, composition, and place <strong>of</strong> residence (as wellas <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> money income).Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1959.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Census.233


TABLE B-18.—Sources and uses <strong>of</strong> gross .«• "ing, 7929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Gross private saving and government surplus ordeficit, national income and product accountsGross investmentYear or quarterTotalTotalPrivate savingPersonalbusi-Grosssaving nesssavingGovernment surplusor deficit (-)TotalFederalStateandlocalTotalGrossprivate Netdomesticin-invest-foreignvest-mentment iStatisticaldiscrepancy192916.315.34.211.21.01.2-0.217.016.20.80.71930...193119321933193419351936193719381939 .11.85.1.8.93.26.67.211.97.08.812.18.02.52.35.68.610.311.58.711.03.42.6-.6-.9.42.13.63.8.72.68.65.33.23.25.26.46.77.78.08.4-.3-2.9-1.8-1.4-2.4-2.0-3.1.3-1.8-2.2.3-2.1-1.5-1.3-2.9-2.6-3.6-.4-2.1-2.2-.6-.8-.3-.1.5.6.5.7.4*11.05.81.11.63.86.48.411.87.610.210.35.61.01.43.36.48.511.86.59.3.7.2.2.2.4-.1-.1.11.1.9—.8.736.5-.21 261.31940194119421..194319441945...19461947 .1948...194913.618.610.75.52.55.235.142.049.935.914.322.442.049.754.344.729.727.541.439.03.811.027.633.437.329.615.27.313.49.410.511.414.516.317.115.114.520.228.029.7-.7-3.8-31.4-44.1-51.8-39.55.414.48.5-3.2-1.3-5.1-33.1-46.6-54.5-42.13.513.48.4-2.4.61.31.82.52.72.61.91.0-.714.619.09.63.55.09.135.242.947.936.213.117.99.85.77.110.630.634.046.035.71.51.1-.2-2.2-2.1-1.44.68.91.9.51 0.4-1.1-2.02.53.9.1.9-2.0.319501951..-1952... .19531954 „____19551956.....1957...19581959.... . .50.456.149.547.548.564.872.771.259.273.842.550.353.354.455.662.167.870.571.775.913.117.318.118.316.415.820.620.722.319.129.433.135.136.139.246.347.349.849.456.87.85.8-3.8-6.9-7.02.74.9.7-12.5-2.19.16.2-3.8-7.0-5.94.05.72.1-10.2-1.2-1.2-.4*.1-1.1-1.3-.9-1.4-2.3-.851.859.551.650.551.366.971.671.260.773.054.159.351.952.651.767.470.067.860.975.3-2.2.2-.3-2.1-.5-.51.53.4-.2-2.31.53.32.23.02.72.1-1.1 *1.6-.8196019611962 .19631964 .. . _ _19651966P77.575.585.090.5100.1112.373.979.887.988.7101.4109.12 115.117.021.221.619.924.525.726.956.858.766.368.876.983.42 88. 23.7-4.3-2.91.8-1.43.22 3. 53.5-3.8-3.8.7-3.01.62.2• .2-.5.91.21.71.62 3.376.574.785.590.398.7110.7118.474.871.783.087.193.0106.6116.53.02.53.15.74.21.9-1.0-.8.5-.3-1.4-1.62 —.2Seasonally adjusted annual rate1964: IIIIIIIV96.097.4100.4106.696.9103.1101.2104.522.026.622.826.674.976.578.477.9-0.9-5.7-.82.1-1.9-6.7-3.0-.51.01.12.22.696.596.898.2103.390.291.892.597.46.35.05.75.90.4-.6-2.3-3.31965:1-_IIIIIIV111.7110.9111.8115.0105.3104.8112.8113.622.822.429.028.582.582.483.885.16.46.1-1.01.44.54.4-2.5-.21.91.71.51.6107.6108.8110.9115.4103.8103.7106.7111.93.85.14.23.5-4.1-2.1-.8.41966:1IIIII.IV P ...117.9121.2115.8113.2113.9112.526.726.624.529.986.587.388.04.77.33.32.33.8-.52.43.53.8117.1120.3116.1120.1114.5118.5115.0118.02.61.81.12.1-.8-.9.41 Net exports <strong>of</strong> goods and services less net transfers to foreigners.2 Data for corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its are approximations for <strong>the</strong> year as a whole; data for fourth quarter are notavailable. All o<strong>the</strong>r data incorporating or derived from <strong>the</strong>se figures are correspondingly approximate.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.234


POPULATION, EMPLOYMENT, WAGES, AND PRODUCTIVITYTABLE B-19.—Population by age groups: Estimates, 1929-66, and projections, 7970-85[Thousands <strong>of</strong> persons]Age (years)July 1TotalUnder 55-1314-1920-2425-4445-6465 andoverEstimates:192919301931193219331934121, 767123,077124,040124,840125,579126,37411,73411,37211,17910,90310,61210,33122,13122,26622,26322, 23822,12921,96413,79613,93713,98014,01514,07014,16310, 69410,91511,00311,07711,15211,23835,86236,30936,65437,31937,66221,07621,57322,03122,47322,93323,4356,4746,7057,1477,3637,58219351936193719381939127,250128,053128,825129,825130,88010,17010,04410,00910,17610,41821, 73021,43421,08220,66820, 25314,29614,44214,55814,68014,74811,31711,37511,41111,45311, 51937,98738,28838,58938,95439,35423,94724,44424,91725,38725,8237,8048,0278,2588,5088,76419401941194219431944132,122133,402134,860136,739138,39710,57910,85011,30112,01612, 52419,93619,67419,42719,31919, 24614,77014,68214,53414,38114, 26411,69011,80711,95512,06412, 06239,86840,38340,86141,42042,01626, 24926, 71827,19627,67128,1389,0319,2889,5849,86710,14719451946194719481949139,928141,389144,126146, 631149,18812,97913, 24414,40614,91915, 60719,32619, 62520,11820,99021, 63413,94213,59713,44713,17113,00612, 03612,00411,81411, 79411, 70042,52143,02743, 65744,28844,91628,63029,06429,49829,93130,40510,49410,82811,18511,53811, 92119501951195219531954152,271154,878157, 553160,184163, 02616,41017,33317,31217,63818,05722,42422, 99824, 50125, 70126,88712,83912,72712,80712, 98613,23011,68011, 55211,35011,06210,83245,67346,10346,49446, 78647,00230,84931,36231,88432,39332,94112,39712,80313,20313,61714,07619551956195719581959165,931168,903171,984174,882177,83018,56619,00319,49419,88720,17527,92528,92929,67230, 65131,76713, 50113,98114,79515,33715,81610,71410,61610,60310,75647,19547,38047, 44147,33647,19233, 50734,05834,59135,10935,66314,52714,93715,38715,80516,2481960196119621963196419651966Projections: 21970: Series A..Series D_.180,684183,756186, 656189,417192,1201194, 583196,842208,615204,92320,36420.65720,74620,75020, 69120,43419,85121,31717,62532,98533,29633.94334,60635,29835,88836, 52537,22437,22416,21717,56618,48319.07519,81320,63821, 57923,13623,13611,11611,40811,88912, 62013,15213,66714,047]• 17,26147,13447.06146,93346,87446,79046, 79248,27636,20836.75637,31637,86838,43439, 01139,59241,81716,65917,01317.31117,56517,85618,15618,45719,5851975: Series A...Series D..227,929215,36727,21018,32337,88434,20925,13225,132} 19,29953,88243,36321,1591980: Series A...Series D_.250,489227,66531,04020,73645,21532,69524,62124,621} 20,99762,37343,17923,0631985: Series A...Series D__274,748241,73123,03053,49735,93326,89421,699} 21,06872,08342,94124,9771 The latest estimate for total population for 1965 is 194,572,000 (as shown in Table B-16), but detail by agegroups is not yet available.2 Two <strong>of</strong> four series projected by <strong>the</strong> cohort method and based on different assumptions with regard tocompleted fertility, which moves gradually toward a level <strong>of</strong> 3,350 children per 1,000 women for Series Aand 2,450 children per 1,000 women for Series D. For fur<strong>the</strong>r explanation <strong>of</strong> method <strong>of</strong> projection and foradditional data, see forthcoming Population Estimates, Current Population <strong>Report</strong>s, Series P-25.NOTE.—Data for armed forces overseas included beginning 1940 and for Alaska and Hawaii beginning 1950.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Census.235


TABLE B-20.—Noninstitutional population and <strong>the</strong> labor force, 1929-66Year or monthNoninstitutionalTotallaborforce(includingarmedforces)iArmedforces 1Civilian labor forceTotalEmployment 2TotalAgriculturalNonagriculturalUnemployment2Totallaborforce aspercent<strong>of</strong> noninstitutionallationUnemploymentas percent<strong>of</strong>civilianlaborforceOld definitions 21929-1930.1931-1932-1933.1934.1935-1936.1937.1940.1941.1942.1943.1944.1945.1946.1947.New definitions 21947.1948.1949.1950-1951.1952.1953.1954.1955.1956.1957.1958-1959.Thousands <strong>of</strong> persons 14 years <strong>of</strong> age and over1960Including Alaska andHawaii19601961196231962196319641965.1966 _1965: Jan...Feb...Mar..Apr...May..June..July..Aug..Sept..Oct—Nov..Dec...100,380101,520102,610103,660104,630105,530106,520107,608107,608108,632109,773110,929112,075113,270115,094116,219117,388118,734120,445121,950123,366124,878125,368127,852130,081130,081132,124134,143136,241138,385135,302135,469135,651135,812135,982136,160136,252136,473136,670136,862137,043137,22649,44050,08050,68051,25051,84052,49053,14053,74054,32054,95055,60056,18057,53064,56066,04065,30060,97061,75861,75863,72164,74965,98366,56067,36267,81870,38770,74471,28471,94672,82073,12674,17574,84074,68175.71276,97178,35780,16475.69976,41876,61277,30778,42580,68381,15080,16378,04478.71378,59878,4772602602602502502602703003203403705401,6203,9709,02011,41011,4403,4501,5901,5901,4561,6161,6503,0993,5943,5473,3503,0482,8572,7982,6372,5522,5142,5142,5722,8272,8272,7372,7382,7223,1232,7072,7042,7032,6862,6842,6802,6932,6932,7232,7602,7952,84149,18049,82050,42051,00051,59052,23052,87053,44054,00054,61055,23055,64055,91056,41055,54054,63053,86057,52060,16860,16861,44262,10562,88462,96663,81564,46865,84867,53067,94668,64770,30670,61271,60372,01371,85472,97574,23375,63577,04172,99273,71473,90974,62175,74178,00378,45777,47075,32175,95375,80375,63647,63045,48042,40038,94038,76040,89042,26044,41046,30044,22045,75047,52050,35053,75054,47053,96052,82055,25058,02757,81259,11758,42359,74860,78461,03561,94560,89062,94464,70865,01163,96665,58166,39266,68166,79668,00067,84668,80970,35772,17974,06568,99669,49670,16971,07072,40773,71674,85474,21272,44673,19672,83772,74910,45010,34010,29010,17010,0909,90010,11010,0009,8209,6109,5409,1009,2509,0808,9508,5808,3208,2668,2567,9608,0177,4977,0486,7926,5556,4956,7186,5726,2225,8445,8365,6965,7235,4635,2595,1904,9464,7614,5854,2063,7393,8033.9894,4735,1285,6225,6265,1364,7784,9544,1283,64537,18035,14032,11028,77028,67030,99032,15034,41036,48034,53036,14037,98041,25044,50045,39045,01044,24046,93049,76149,55751,15650,40652,25153,73654,24355,39054,39556,22558,13558,78958,12259,74560,69760,95861,33362,74462,65763,86365,59667,59465,25765,69466,18066,59767,27868,09469,22869,07767,66868,24268,70969,1031,5504,3408,02012,06012,83011,34010,6109,0307,70010,3909,4808,1205,5602,6601,0706701,0402,2702,1422,3562,3253,6823,3512,0991,9321,8703,5782,9042,8222,9364,6813,8133,9133,9314,8064,0144,0074,1663,8763,4562,9763,9964,2183,7403,5523,3354,2873,6023,2582,8752,7572,9662,888Percent56.056.758.862.363.161.957.257.457.457.958.058.458.958.858.558.458.759.358.758.558.358.358.358.057.557.457.357.457.557.955.956.456.556.957.759.359.658.757.157.557.457.2See footnotes at end <strong>of</strong> table.236


TABLE B-20.—Noninstitutional population and <strong>the</strong> labor force, 7929-66—ContinuedYear or monthTotalNonin-laborstitu-tional (includ-forceArmedpopulation» armedingforces 1forces) 1TotalCivilian labor forceTotalEmployment 2AgriculturalNonagriculturalUnemployment2Totallaborforce aspercent<strong>of</strong> noninstitutionalpopulationUnemploymentas percent<strong>of</strong>civilianlaborforceThousands <strong>of</strong> persons 14 years <strong>of</strong> age and overPercent1966: Jan..Feb.Mar.Apr.MayJune.137,394137,562137,741137,908138,100138,27577,40977,63278,03478,91479,75182,7002,8902,9242,9743,0083,0453,09974,51974,70875,06075,90676,70679,60171,22971,55172,02373,10573,76475,7313,5773,6123.7804,2044,2925,18767,65267,93968,24468,90069,47270,5433,2903,1583,0372,8022,9423,87056.356.456.757.257.759.84.44.24.03.73.84.9July.Aug_Sept.Oct..Nov.Dec.138,444138,648139,041139,237139,42982,77182,46880,05280,53080,96880,7343,1353,1783,2293,2793,3223,39079,63679,29076,82377,25177,64677,34476,41176,36974,25174,73075.00674,6125,0104,7074,3734,3013,9693,46571,40271,66269,87870,43071,03671,1473,2252,9212,5732,5212,6402,73259.557.757.958.257.94.03.73.33.33.43.5Seasonally adjusted1965: JanFebMarAprMayJune77,58877,77077,72277,98877,99078,33274,88175,06675,01975,30275,30675,65271,25271,32671,48371,68871,81672,0854,5334,6084,5884,7694,8694,65166,71966,71866,89566,91966,94767,4343,6293,7403,3,6143,4903,5674.85.04.74.84.64.7JulyAugSept.OctNovDec1966: JanFebMarAprMayJuneJulyAugSeptOctNovDec78,74778,46578,33478,60678,91679,40879,64479,27979, 31579, 67479, 31380,18580, 23380, 54980, 34280, 41481, 24981,57976,054 72,61875, 772 72,38775,611 72,29775,846 72,56176, 111 72,91476,567 73,44176,75476,35576, 34176,66676,26877, 08677,09877,37177,11377,13577,92778,18973,71573, 52173, 43573,79973,23173,99774, 07274,33874,16574,16375, 07675,2264,6394,5724,4184,5514,2734,4864,4294,4424,r4,4824,0764,2384,1444,1584,0493,9714,1084,25467,97967,81567,87968,01068,64168,95569, 28669, 07969, 07269, 31769,15569,75969,92870,18070,11670,19270.96870,9723,4363,3853,3143,2853,1973,1263,0392,8342,9062,8673,0373,0893,0263,0332,9482,9722,8512,9634.54.54.44.34.24.14.03.73.83.74.04.03.93.93.83.93.73.81 Data for 1940-52 revised to include about 150,000 members <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> armed forces who were outside <strong>the</strong>United States in 1940 and who were, <strong>the</strong>refore, not enumerated in <strong>the</strong> 1940 Census and were excluded from<strong>the</strong> 1940-52 estimates.2 See Note.3 Averages adjusted by Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers for comparison with preceding data. See Note.NOTE.—Civilian labor force data beginning with January 1963 are based on a 357-area sample. ForJanuary 1960-December 1962 on a 333-area sample; for May 1956-December 1959 on a 330-area sample; forJanuary 1954-April 1956 on a 230-area sample; for 1946-53 on a 68-area sample; for 1940-45 on a smaller sample;and for 1929-39 on sources o<strong>the</strong>r than direct enumeration.Effective January 1957, persons on lay<strong>of</strong>f with definite instructions to return to work within 30 days <strong>of</strong>lay<strong>of</strong>f and persons waiting to start new wage and salary jobs within <strong>the</strong> following 30 days are classifiedas unemployed. Such persons had previously been classified as employed (with a job but not at work).The combined total <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> groups changing classification has averaged about 200,000 to 300,000 a month inrecent years. The small number <strong>of</strong> persons in school during <strong>the</strong> survey week and waiting to start newjobs are classified as not in <strong>the</strong> labor force instead <strong>of</strong> employed, as formerly. Persons waiting to open newbusinesses or start new farms within 30 days continue to be classified as employed.Beginning July 1955, monthly data are for <strong>the</strong> calendar week ending nearest <strong>the</strong> 15th <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> month; previously,for week containing <strong>the</strong> 8th. Annual data are averages <strong>of</strong> monthly figures.Beginning April 1962, estimating procedures make use <strong>of</strong> 1960 Census data; for January 1953-March 19621950 Census data were used, and 1940-52,1940 Census data. For <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> this change on <strong>the</strong> historicalcomparability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> data, see Employment and Earnings, May 1962, p. xiv.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics (except as noted).240-782 O—67- -16 237


TABLE B-21.—Civilian employment and unemployment, by sex and age, 1947-66[Thousands <strong>of</strong> persons 14 years <strong>of</strong> age and over]EmploymentUnemploymentYear or monthTotalTotalMales14-19years20yearsand TotalFemales14-19years20 TotalyearsandTotalMales14-19years20yearsand TotalFemales14-19years20yearsandNew definitions *1947..1948-1949.1950.1951.1952.1953.1954.1955.1956.1957.1958.1959.1960 21961.1962 31963.1964.1965.1966.57, 812 41,552 2,776 38,776 16,259 1, , 905 14,35459,117 42,268 2,887 39,381 16,848 1, , 913 14,93558,423 41,473 2,672 38; 803 16; 947 l| 812 15,13759,748 42, 1,162 2,769 39,395 17,584 1,76115,82460,784 42, !,362 2, 738 39,626 18,421 1,85116,57061,035 42,237 . 2,659 39,578 18,798 1, .; 840 " "" 16,95861,945 42,966 2, "!, 671 40,295 18, 979 1, 813 17,16460.890 42,165 2, 530 39,634 18,724 1,724 17,00062,944 43,152 2,626 40, 527 19,790 1,78818,00264,70843,999 2,— 783 41,216 20, 707 1,940 18, 76765,011 43,990 2,750 :, 41,239 21,021 1,970 19,05063j 966 43,042 2,631 !,63140, 40,410 20,9241,881 ... 19,04365,581 44,089 2, !,821 41,268 21,492 1,96819,52344,485 2,941 41,543 22,196 2,09120,1041 2Q566,796 44,318 2,976 41,342 22,478 2,181 20,67,846 44,892 3,077 41,815 " 22,954 2,262 20,68,809 45,330 ""' 3, 1,079 42,252 23,479 2,223 21,25770,357 46,139 3, 1,253 42,886 24,218 2,316 21; ,90372,179 47,034 3,612 43,422 25,145 2,515 22,63174,065 47, 639 3,971 43, 66' 26, 426 2,919 23, 5072,3562,3253,6823,3512,0991,9321,8703,5782,9042,8222,9364,6813,8133,9314,8064,0074,1663,8763,4562,976Seasonally adjusted1,7201,5902,6022,2801,2501,2171,2282,3721,8891,7571,8933,1552,4732,5413,0602,4882,5372,2711,6222982863823592202372093383083153514734514805424725665535455031,4221,3042,2191,9221,0299801,0192,0351,5801,4421,5412,6802,0222,0582,5182,0161,9711,7181,4361,1196377351,0831,0738517156421,2071,0161,0671,0431,5261,3401,3901,7471,5191,6291,6051,4761,3541621702412201621571332101942362222842763103793444134094204354755658418546895595109978238328201,2421,0641,0781,3661,1761,2161,1951.0579191965: Jan...Feb..Mar..Apr..May.June..July....AugSeptOctNovDec1966: Jan...Feb..Mar.Apr_.May-June-July..Aug..Sept..Oct—Nov..Dec-.71, 252 46,585 3, 274 43, 31124,667 2, 280 22,387 3,629326 46, 714 3, 334 43,380 24,612 2, 300 22, 3123,7407i; 483 46,823 3,400 43,423 24,660 2, 324 22, 3363,53671,688 46,968 3,529 43,439 24,720 2, 360 22, 360 3,61471,816 47, 054 3,551 43, 503 24, 762 2,412 22,3503,49072, 085 46,962 3,484 43,478 25,123 2,409 22,714 3,56772,618 47, 228 3,736 43,492 25, 390 2, 56: 22,823 3,43672, 387 47,130 3,677 43,453 25, 257 2, 53122,7263,38572,297 46, 917 3,632 43, 285 25, 380 2,609 22, 7713,31472, 561 47, ; 051 3,817 43,234 25,510 2, 720 22,7903,28572,914 47, 185 3,855 43, 330 25,729 2,792 22,937 3,19773,44147, 500 3,921 43, 579 25,941 2, 784 23,157 3,12673,715 47,624 4, 020 43,604 26, 0912,863 23, 22873,521 47, f73,435 47,173,799 47,814 4, 042 43,772 25,985 2,852 23,13373,23147,344 3,747 *"73,997 47,754 4,133 43; 621 26; 243 2,9572,8342,9062,8673,0373,0892,1062,0992,0122,0702,0632,0092,0131,9521 r~1,7371,7291,7011,5891,6511,5491,6111,69374, 072 47,6514, 066 43,585 26,421 2,996 23,42574,338 47, 766 4, 075 43,691 26,572 3, 045 23,527 1,61374,165 47,345 3,762 43,583 26,820 2,838 23,982 2,948 1,58874,163 47,374 3,834 43,540 26,789 2,921 2,972 1,55375, 076 47, 702 4, 031 43,671 27,374 3,080 24,294 2,851 1,55075, 226 47,9114', 019 43,892 27,315 3, 064 24,2512,9631,6095285044975395705545905405285945025575174464934855475345104715054834685311,5781,5951, 5151,5311,4931,4551,4231,4121,3611,3051,2351,1721,1841,1431,1581,0641,0641,1591,1591,1421,0831,0701,0821,0781,5231,6411,5241,5441,4271,5581,4231,4331,4251^4601,397l,;1,:1,2551,3181,4261,3961,3571,4201,3601,4191,3011,354466454442475401406385380,057,187,082,069,026,1521,0381,0531,0033971 989430 1,030433 9644213744014514654564694664124274143849178718548679619409549489928879701 See Note, Table B-20, for explanation <strong>of</strong> differences between <strong>the</strong> old and new definitions.2 Beginning 1960, data for Alaska and Hawaii included.3 Beginning April 1962, not comparable with preceding data; see Note, Table B-20.Note.—See Note, Table B-20, for information on area sample used and reporting periods.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics.238


TABLE B-22.—Selected unemployment rates, 7948-66[Percent]Year or monthBoth14-19yearsBy sex and ageMen,20yearsandAllworkersWomen,20yearsandoverBy raceWhiteNonwhiteExperiencedwageandsalaryworkersBy selected groupsMarriedmen JFulltimeworkers2Bluecollarworkers3Laborforcetime lostthroughunemploymentand parttimeemployment4New definitions1948194919601951195219531954195519561957195819593.85.95.33.33.12.95.64.44.24.36.85.58.712.211.37.78.07.111.410.210.410.814.413.23.25.44.72.52.42.54.93.83.43.66.24.73.65.35.14.03.22.95.54.44.24.16.15.25.03.93.73.96.14.98.78.48.012.610.74.26.76.03.73.33.26.04.84.44.57.25.63.44.61.51.41.74.02.82.62.85.13.65.45.02.62.55.23.83.74.07.24.28.07.23.93.63.47.25.85.16.210.17.65.15.38.16.61960s19611962 61963196419651966_5.66.75.65.75.24.63.913.615.213.315.614.713.612.04.75.74.64.53.93.22.55.16.35.45.45.24.55.06.04.95.14.64.13.410.212.511.010.99.88.37.55.76.85.55.55.04.23.53.74.63.63.42.82.41.96.75.54.94.33.57.89.27.47.26.35.34.26.78.06.7


TABLE B-23.—Unemployment by duration, 1947-66Year or monthTotal unemployment4 weeksand underDuration <strong>of</strong> unemployment5-14weeks15-26weeksOver26 weeksNew definitions1947 -.1948 _1949195019511952 . _ __ -__1953195419551956 - _195719581959 __ _196011961 -1962 21963196419651966Thousands <strong>of</strong> persons 14 years <strong>of</strong> age and over2,3562,3253,6823,3512,0991,9321,8703,5782,9042,8222,9364,6813,8133,9314,8064,0074,1663,8763,4562,9761,2551,3491,8041,5151,2231,1831,1781,6511,3871,4851,4851,8331,6581,7981,8971,7541,8471,7871,7181,6367046691,1951,0555745174821,115815805890,397] 1,113,1761,3751,134,231,1169838042341934274251661481324953673013217854695027285345354914042951641162563571378479317336232239667571454804585553482351241Seasonallyadjusted1965: Jan - - -.FebMarAprMayJune3,6293,7403,5363,6143,4903,5671,6951,7761,7411,8181,8291,7881.044L, 03010291,0461.015421479439443377419403408361370338360JulyAug - - - -SeptOctNovDec - - -1966: JanFebMarAprMayJune3,4363,3853,3143,2853,1973,1263,0392,8342,9062,8673,0373,0891,7911,7221,7031,5621,6181,5321,5481,5141,5431,6251,7891,816980980858992903869738721787670856815355397384350334355354315319343261251330320344347310305307264269260275225JulyAugSeptOctNovDec3,0263,0332,9482,9722,8512,9631,7101,6661,6261,5441,5151,6269129278078988037662202492982922862732152022012281972281 Beginning January 1960, data for Alaska and Hawaii included.2 Beginning April 1962, not comparable with preceding data; see Note, Table B-20.NOTE.—See Note, Table B-20, for information on area sample used and reporting periods.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics.240


TABLE B-24.—Unemployment insurance programs, selected data, 7940-66Year or monthCoveredemployment*All programsInsuredunemployment(weeklyaverage)2 3Totalbenefitspaid(millions<strong>of</strong> dollars)2 *[nsuredunemployment8InitialclaimsExhaustions5State programsInsured unemploymentas percent<strong>of</strong> coveredemploymentUnadjustedSeasonallyadjustedBenefits paidTotal(millions<strong>of</strong>dollars)0)Averageweeklycheck(dollars)•1940-1941-1942-1943-1944-1945-1946-1947-1948-1949-1950-1951-1952-1953-1954..1955-1956—1957-1958-1960—196119621963196419651966 *1965: JanFeb....Mar....AprMay....June. _.July....AugSept...Oct...NovDec—1966: JanFeb...Mar...AprMay...JuneJuly.Aug.Sept.Oct..Nov.Thousands24,29128,13630,81932,41931,71430,08731,85633,87634,64633,09834,30836,33437,00638,07236,62240, 01842, 75143,43644,41145,72846,33446,26647,77648,43449,63751,58053,70049,32149,31949,83850,64051,18652,08752,28052,61152,71352,71652,81953,431"51,935*>52,127*52,894*>53,79754, 32055,5431,3318426611491117202,8041,8051,4682,4791,6051.0001,0691,0652,0481,3951,3181,5673,2692,0992,0672,9941,946? 1,9731,7531,4501,1232,1352,0661,8631,6221,3161,1821,2621,2351,0891,0301,1331,3961,7391,6791,3811,1129168421,0019808027999551,312534.7358.8350.480.567.2574.91,878.5,785.0, 328.72,269.8, 467. 6862.9, 043.51, 050. 62,291.81, 560. 21,540. 61,913. 04,209.2" 803.03,022.74,358.23,160. 03, 025.92, 749. 22,343.71,900.0273.0265.8294.9242.7179.2169.1160.6160.7150.3128.2143.0184.7226.5230.2240.0166.4136.1123.4121.0152.0114.3100.4122.6171.0Weekly average,thousands1,2828146491471055891,2951,0091,0021,9791,5039691,0249951,8651,2541,2121,4502,5091,6821,9062,2901,783'1,8061,6051,3281,0611,9961,9321,7181,4701,1791,0591,1391,1209819331,0421,3081,6441,5901,3011,0448627939479287547529031,25321416412236291161891872103222362082152183032262262683702813313503027 2982682322043552692222201861912522151731892252903292381711661521562491731451662082995030214253824203736161815342520235033314632302621152525252724221918171615171919181917151412111212135.6Percent3.02.2.5.42.14.33.13.06.24.62.82.92.85.23.53.23.66.44.44.85.64.44.33.83.02.34.64.54.03.42.72.42.62.52.22.02.33.03.73.62.92.31.91.82.12.01.61.61.92.748.83.28.2S.OS.OS.O3.12.92.72.72.72.72.62.82.12.12.1II2.12.2518.7344.3344.179.662.4445.9,094.9775.1789.9, 736. 0, 373.1840.4998.2962.22, 026.9,350.3, 380.7, 733.93, 512. 7" 279.02,726.73,422. 72, 675. 42,774.7,522.12,166. 01,780.0252.1245.7273.4224.9165.7156.3149.5148.0138.6117.8132.2172.1212.7217.2225.5155.5126.1114.4113.8143.1106.593.7114.8162.510.5611.0612.6613.8415.9018.7718.5017.8319.0320.4820.7621.0922.7923.5824.9325.0427.0228.1730.5830.4132.8733.8034.5635.2835.9637.1939.7237.1837.3937.4137.1636.4036.0736.4036.5837.2337.3238.0838.8138.7239.0540.6539.8440.5741.002.41 Includes persons under <strong>the</strong> State, UCFE (Federal employee, effective January 1955), and RRB (RailroadRetirement Board) programs. Beginning October 1958, also includes <strong>the</strong> UCX program (unemploymentcompensation for ex-servicemen).2 Includes State, UCFE, RR, UCX, UCV (unemployment compensation for veterans, October 1952-January 1960), and SRA (Servicemen's Readjustment Act, September 1944-September 1951) programs.Also includes Federal and State programs for temporary extension <strong>of</strong> benefits from June 1958 through June1962, expiration date <strong>of</strong> program.3 Covered workers who have completed at least 1 week <strong>of</strong> unemployment.4 Includes benefits paid under extended duration provisions <strong>of</strong> State laws, beginning June 1958. Annualdata are net amounts and monthly data are gross amounts.8 Individuals receiving final payments in benefit year.8 For total unemployment only.7 Programs include Puerto Rican sugarcane workers for initial claims and insured unemployment beginningJuly 1963.8 Preliminary; June 1966 is latest month for which data are available for all programs combined.Workers covered by State programs account for about 87 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included for all periods and for Puerto Rico beginning January 1961.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Bureau <strong>of</strong> Employment Security.241


TABLE B-25.—Number <strong>of</strong> wage and salary workers in nonagi'{cultural establishments, 7929-66 l[Thousands <strong>of</strong> employees]Year ormonth19291930.1931-1932 _1933.1934.1935193619371940.1941.1942.1943.1944.1945.1946.1947.1948.1949-1950-1951.1952.1953.1954.1955.1956 _1957.1958.1959 _I960..1961. .1962..1963..1964..1965. .1966 P.Totalwageandsalaryworkers31,33929,42426,64923,62823,71125,95327,05329| 08231,02629,20930,61832,37636,55440,125142,45241,883'40,394]41,67443,88144,89143,77845,22247,84948,82550,23249,02250,67552,40852,89451,36353,31354,23454,04255,59656,70258,33260,77063,863ManufacturingTotal10,70219,5628,170|6,9317,3978,5019,82710,7949,44010,27810,98513,19215,28017,60217,32815,52414,70315,54515,58214,44115,24116,39316,632117,54916,31416,88217,24317,17415,945|16,67516,79616,32616,85316,99517,27418,03219,0841Durablegoods4,7155,3636,9688,82311,08410,8569,0747,7428,3858,3267,4898,09410; 1109,1299,5419,8349,8568,8309,3739,4599,0709,4809,616!9,81610,38611,190Nondurablegoods5,5645,6226,2256,4586,5186,4726,4506,9627,1597,2566,9537,1477,3047,2847,4387,1857,3407,4097,3197,1167,3037,3367,2567,3737,3807,4587,6457,895Miningl,087|'8737317448838979461,015891854925957992925892862955994901866791792]822828|751,732|712672650635634632628ContractconstructionTransportationandpublicutilities1,4971,3721,2149708098629121,1451,1121,0551,1501,2941,7902,1701,5671,0941,1321,6611,9822,1692,1652,3332,6032,6342,6122,8022,9992,9232,7782,9602,8852,8162,9022,9633,0503,1813,281Whole-1saleandretailtrade3,91613,6853,2542,8162,6722,7502,7862,9733,1342,8632,9363,0383,2743,4603,6473,8293,9064,0614,16614,1894,0014,0344,2264,2484,2904,0844,1414,2444,2413,9764, Oil'4,0043,9033,9063,9033,9514,0334,136Finance,insurance,andrealestate6,1235,7975,2844,683|4,755[5,2815,4315,8096,2656,1796,4266,7507,2107,1186,9827,0587,3148,3768,9559,2729,2649,74210,00410,24710,23510,53510,85810,88610,75011,12711,39111,33711,56611,77812,16012,68313,2191,509,475,407,341,295,319,432,425,462,502,549,538,502,476,497,,697,754,829,857,919,9912,0692,1462,2342,3352,4292,4772,5192,5942,6692,7312,8002,8772,9573, 019!3,085Serviceandmiscellaneous3,4403,3763,1832,9312,8733,05813,1423,5183,4733,5173,6813,9214,0844,1484,163|4,2414,7195,0505,2065,2645,3825,5765,7305,8676,0026,2746,5366,7496,8067,1307,4237,6648,0288,3258,7099,581GovernmentFederal5335265605595656527538268338299059961,3402,2132,9052,9282,808|2,2541,9081,9282,3022,4202,3052,1882,1872,2092,2172,1912,2332,2702,2792,3402,3582,3482,3782,566Stateandlocal2,5322,6222,7042,6662,6012,6472,7282,8422,9233,0543,0903,2063,3203,2703,1743,1163,1373,3413,5823,7873,9484,0984,0874,1884,3404,5634,7275,0695', 6485,8506,3156,5506,8687,2497,713See footnotes at end <strong>of</strong> table.242


TABLE B-25.—Number <strong>of</strong> wage and salary workers in nonagricultural establishments,1929-661—Continued[Thousands <strong>of</strong> employees]Year ormonthTotalManufacturingTotalwageandsalaryworkersDurablegoodsNondurablegoodsMiningContractconstructionTransportationandpublicutilitiesWholesaleandretailtradeFinance,insurance,andrealestateGovernmentServiceandmiscellaneousFederalStateandlocalSeasonally adjusted1964: JanFebMarAprMayJuneJuly....AugSeptOctNov....Dec1965: JanFebMarMay"."." IJuneJuly....AugSeptOctNov....Dec1966: JanFebMarAprJuneMayJuly....AugSeptOctNov *..-Dec*...57,33657,67657,80057,94258,06158,21158,36958,52158,74758,64959,11859,38759,48959,77760,07260,15260,36360,62360,84161,02161,18061,43761,86462,24162,46962,81163,24763,35063,51763,98364,07264,19964,16864,46664,81865,06617,08517, 11117,15917,18317,19717,23117,26817,32517,45617,19817,51317,60017,66717,72117,80717,85017,88517,99018,06918,12918,15718,24218,39218,49218,56618,72218,84018,92319,00219,16719,12819,26219,20419,31219,42219,4659,6929,7009,7529,7649,7589,7769,8169,8579,9719,7049,97810,05210,09910,14210,20310,25010,27710,34810,41810,48310,50810,55010,64110,72510,80510,91111,00711,06511,12211,22011,21011,32411,32211,38711,43411,4717,3937,4117,4077,4197,4397,4557,4527,4687,4857,4947,5357,5487,5687,5797,6047,6007,6087,6427,6517,6467,6497,6927,7517,7677,7617,8117,8337,8587,8807,9477,9187,9387,8827,9257,9887,9946306316326336306386386336336366386386366366356336306306356316226276316336356346375956286326366366286256236272,8653,0543,0563,0303,0293,0493,0573,0553,0473,0733,1103,1473,1413,1773,2053,1183,1573,1693,1323,1623,1683,1863,2343,3343,3183,3233,4193,3333,2383,3003,2973,2513,2283,2023,2123,2823,9163,9243,9203,9413,9423,9363,9523,9603,9673,9703,9794,0083,9423,9844,0154,0134,0254,0334,0364,0504,0644,0714,0804,0834,0914,1054,1094,1144,1324,1434,1224,1054,1684,1654,1934,19411,95212,00612,00912,04712,08512,13612,19212,22912,24712,28612,30712,36412,42012,48512,53012,57912,62312,67012,71412,71712,76512,80912,88012,94113,00913,04513,08513,12813,16413, 21713,25613,26413,26813,34013,38013,3902,9242,9332,9432,9472,9522,9572,9642,9632,9712,9742,9802,9802,9852,9932,9993,0023,0113,0163,0213,0303,0363,0413,0453,0493,0523,0513,0643,0683,0763,0903,0953,1003,1003,1023.1093,1198,5348,5698,5918,6318,6758,7038,7428,7658,7958,8188,8328,8628,8898,9298,9769,0059,0429,0609,1239,1529,1809,2269,2829,3299,3639,4109,4639,4849,5159,5499,6099,6479,6499,7129,7809,8142,3422,3402,3392,3412,3412,3252,3222,3282,3252,3342,3522,3512,3422,3382,3422,3442,3472,3552,3742,3792,3782,3862,4002,3972,4232,4512,4772,5012,5232,5712,6012,6102,5942,6152,6212,6387,0887,1087,1517,1897,2107,2367,2347,2637,3067,3607,4077,4377,4677,5147,5637,6087,6437,7007,7377,7717,8107,8497,9207,9838,0128,0708,1538,2048,2398,3148,3288,3248,3298,3938,4788,5371 Includes all full- and part-time wage and salary workers in nonagricultural establishments who workedduring, or received pay for, any part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> pay period which includes <strong>the</strong> 12th <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> month. Excludesproprietors, self-employed persons, domestic servants, and unpaid family workers. Not comparable wi<strong>the</strong>stimates <strong>of</strong> nonagricultural employment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> civilian labor force (Table B-20) which include proprietors,self-employed persons, domestic servants, and unpaid family workers; which count persons as employedwhen <strong>the</strong>y are not at work because <strong>of</strong> industrial disputes, bad wea<strong>the</strong>r, etc.; and which are based on asample survey <strong>of</strong> households, whereas <strong>the</strong> estimates in this table are based on reports from employingestablishments.NOTE.—Data are based on <strong>the</strong>" 1957 Standard Industrial Classification and March 1965 benchmark data.Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1959.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics.243


1929..1930...1931..1932 _.1933..1934..1935..1936..1937. .1938. -1940..1941..1942..1943..1944..1945..1946 ..1947 ..1948..1949..1950..1951..1952..1953..1954..1955.,1956..1957..1958..1959..1960. .1961. .1962..1963..1964..1965...1966P...TABLE B-26.—Average weekly hours <strong>of</strong> work in selected industries, 1929-66Year or month1965: JanFeb....Mar....AprMay...June—.July....Aug.—Sept—.OctNov....Dec1966: JanFeb....Mar....AprMay...June-July..-Aug...Sept...Oct....Nov.Dec *_.Total44.242.140.538.338.134.636.639.238.635.637.738.140.643.145.045.243.540.340.440.039.140.540.640.740.539.640.740.439.839.240.339.739.840.440.540.741.241.441.141.241.341.041.241.041.041.141.041.241.441.341.441.541.541.541.541.341.041.441.541.341.341.0ManufacturingDurablegoods32.534.733.837.240.939.934.937.939.242.045.046.546.544.040.440.540.439.441.141.541.541.240.141.341.040.339.540.740.140.340.941.141.442.042.142.142.042.241.842.041.941.941.841.742.142.242.242.442.442.342.342.242.041.842.142.342.242.041.9Nondurablegoods41.940.035.136.137.737.436.137.437.038.940.342.543.142.340.540.239.638.939.739.539.739.639.039.939.639.238.839.739.239.339.639.639.740.140.238.238.137.737.438.138.937.937.237.137.537.036.837.036.736.937.037.337.237.437.5Seasonally adjusted40.140.140.239.840.040.040.040.040.140.140.340.240.240.540.440.340.340.340.140.240.240.240.240.037.637.437.537.037.437.137.437.336.437.137.238.637.838.138.537.236.137.437.836.937.737.337.138.8Retailtrade43.443.242.841.840.941.040.941.341.040.941.041.140.940.539.839.739.639.138.738.738.738.538.137.937.8«37.036.635.936.836.836.836.936.836.636.736.636.536.436.336.336.236.136.035.935.936.036.136.135.835.735.735.6ContractconstructionWholesaletrade41.642.943.142.341.841.341.141.442.343.042.841.641.141.040.840.740.840.740.640.540.740.540.340.240.640.540.540.640.640.640.840.740.840.840.840.740.940.840.840.940.840.940.840.941.040.940.840.740.740.640.940.840.740.740.640.5Bituminouscoalmining38.133.328.127.029.326.826.228.527.723.326.827.830.732.436.343.042.041.340.337.732.334.734.933.834.132.337.337.536.333.335.835.835.9


Year or month19291930193119321933193419351936193719381939194019411942194319441945194619471948_1949195019511952195319541955 _ .195619571958 _1959196019611962_ _1963196419651966v _ _ ,1965: JanFebMarAprMayJuneJulyAugSept _ .OctNovDec1966: JanFebMarAprMayJuneJuly ._ .AugSeptOctNov vDec*TABLE B—27.—Average gross hourly earnings in selected industries, 7929-66Total$0,560546.509.441.437.526.544550.617.620.627.655.726.851.flS7L.011L.016L 075.2171.328L.3781.440L.561.651.74L. 781.861.952.052.112.192.262.322.392.462.532.612.712.582.592.592.602.612.612.612.592.632.642.652.662.672.672.682.702.702.712.712.702.742.752.762.77ManufacturingDurablegoods$0,492.467.550.571580.667.679.691.716.799.9371.0481.1051.0991.144L. 278L.395L.453L.519L.65L. 751.86.901.992.082.192.262.362.432.492.562.632.712.792.892.762.772.782.782.792.792.792.772.812.822.832.842.852.862.862.882.882.882.882.872.932.942.942.95Nondurablegoods$0,412.419.505.520519.566.572.571.590.627.709.787.844.886.9951.1451.2501.2951.3471.441.511.581.621.671.771.851.911.982.052.112.172.222.292.362.452.332.332.342.342.352.352.362.362.382.382.392.402.402.412.412.432.442.452.462.452.472.482.492.50$1.5411.7131.7921.8632.022.132.282.392.452.572.712.822.933.083.203.313.413.553.693.873.633.693.663.623.663.673.653.693.753.773.753.773.793.823.803.813.833.833.853.893.963.953.953.97Retailtrade$.484.494.518.559.606.653.699.797.901.9721.015.050.13.18'. L.251.29.3440.47L52L.57L.621L. 68L.74806 L.75L82191L79.79L79.80.82.82.82.82.84.86.86.85.88.88.88.89.90.91.91.90.93.941.951.93ContractconstructionWholesaletrade$0,610628.658.674.688.711.763.828.898.948.9901.1071.2201.3081.3601.4271.521.611.701.761.831.942.022.092.182.242.312.372.452.522.612.732.562.582.582.592.612.592.602.602.622.632.652.662.662.682.692.722.732.722.732.732.752.772.782.78Bituminouscoalmining$0.659662.626.503.485651.720768.828.849.858.854.9601.0301.1011.1471.1991.3571.5821.8351.8771.9442.142.222.402.402.472.722.922.933.113.143.125 3.125 3.155 3.308 3. 493.643.463.483.463.473.503.513.523.503.503.513.513.533.543.523.433.723.723.703.743.763.76Class Irailroads*$0.730.733.743.837.852.948.9551.0871.1861.3011.4271.5721.731.831.881.931.962.122.262.442.542.612.672.722.762.803.002.993.032.972.983.012.993.002.993.013.013.012.993.093.133.053.083.083.073.09Telephonecom-$0.774.816.822.827.820.843.870.9114 .9621.1241.1971.2481.3451.3981.491.591.681.761.821.861.952.052.182.262.372.482.562.622 702.782.672.672.672.682 692.692.672.682.732.732.752.782.762.782.772.772.772.782.772.762.792.802.81munica-tionsAgriculture3$0,241.226.172.129115.129.142152.172166.166.169.206.268.353.423.472515.547.580.559.561.625.661.672661.675.705728.757.798.818834.856.880.9049511 0301.0101 For coverage <strong>of</strong> series, see footnote 1, Table B-26. '2 Prior to April 1945, data relate to all employees except executives; for April 1945-May 1949, mainly to employeessubject to <strong>the</strong> Fair Labor Standards Act; and beginning June 1949, to nonsupervisory employees only.3 Weighted average <strong>of</strong> all farm wage rates on a per hour basis.4 Nine-month average, April through December, because <strong>of</strong> new series started in April 1945.5 Eleven-month average; excludes data for July.8 Beginning 1964, data include eating and drinking places. Comparable figure excluding eating anddrinking places is $1.87 for 1964; $1.96 for 1965; and $2.04 for 1966.NOTE.—See Note, Table B-25.Data are for production workers in manufacturing and mining, for construction workers in contract construction,and for all nonsupervisory employees in o<strong>the</strong>r industries (except as noted). Data are for payperiod which includes <strong>the</strong> 12th <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> month.Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1959.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics, and Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture..860.929.9841.060.9451.0101.070245


TABLE B-28.—Average gross weekly earnings in selected industries, 1929-66Year or monthTotalManufacturingDurablegoodsNondurablegoodsRetailtradeContractconstructionWholesaletradeBituminouscoalminingClass Irailroads*19291S301931193219331934193519361937193819391940194119421943194419451946194719481949195019511952 __19531954195519561957195819591960196119621963196419651966 P1965: Jan.Feb.Mar_Apr.MayJuneJuly_Aug.Sept.O£t-Nov.Dec.1966: Jan.Feb.Mar.May.JuneJuly.Aug.Sept.Oct_NovD$24.7623.0020.6416.8916.6518.2019.9121.5623.8222.0723.6424.9629.4836.6843.0745.7044.2043.3249.1753.1258.3263.3467.1670.4770.4975.7078.7881.5982.7188.2689.7292.3496.5699.63102.97107. 53112.19105. 52106.19106. 71105.82107. 53107.79107.01106.45107.83109. 03109.71110.92110.00110. 27110.95111. 24112.05112. 74111.11111. 78113. 71113.85113.99114.68$26.8424.4220.9815.9916.2018.5921.2423.7226.6123.7026.1928.0733.5642.1748.7351.3848.3646.2251.7656.3657.2562.4368.4872.6376.6376.1982.1985.2888.2689.2796.0597.44100.35104.70108.09112.19117.18121.67115.37115. 79117. 04115.93117.46117. 74116. 34115.51117.18118.72119.43120.98119.99120.69120.69121. 54121.82121.82119.81120.54123.94124.07123. 48124.79$22.4721.4020.0917.2616.7617.7318.7719.5721.1720.6521.3621.8324.3928.5733.4536.3837.4840.3046.0349.5050.3853.4856.8859.9562.5763.1866.6370.0972.5274.1178.6180.3682.9285.9387.9190.9194.6498.4992.5092.7393.6092.2094.0094.4794.8795.1195.6895.6896.3296.9695.5296.8896.8896.9698.3399.2399.1499.2399.5499.94100.10100.50$58.8765.2767.5669.6876.9686.4188.9190.9096.38100.27103.78108.41113.04118.08122.47127.19132.06138. 01145.13131.77131.73134.32132.85140.18139. 46140. 89143. 54138.75144.39136.50139.87138.34139.05143.26140. 59141. 71146.69150.15149.38151.67152.08143.39147.68$21.0121.3422.1723.3724.7926.7728.5932.9236.9439.7541.6243.1646.2247.7949.7551.2153.0654.7456,8958.8260.7662.3764.0165.9568.044 64.7566.6168.5765.3465.3465.3466.0666.4366.9868.2568.0767.1667.3366.7767.7167.4967.3067.1267.4767.6469.1470.4870.1169.0968.8768.8469.29$26.7525.1925.4425.3826.9628.3628.5128.7629.3631.3634.2837.9940.7642.3746.0550.1453.6355.4958.0862.0265.5369.0271.2874.4878.5781.4184.0288.5190.7293.5696.2299.47102.31106. 49111. 11103.94104. 49105.01105.15106. 75105.93106. 60106. 34106.90107. 57108.12109.59108.53109.08109.48110.43111.11110.70112.20111.38111. 93112.74112.87113.42$25.1122.0417.5913.5814.2117.4518.8621.8922.9419.7822.9923.7429.4733.3739.9749.3250.3656.0463.7569.1860.6367.4674.6975.0481.8477.5292.13102.00106.0097.57111.34112.41112.01114.46121.43128.91140. 23147.45138.40138. 50137.36137.07141.40145. 67137.11144. 67137.90146.30131.98146.37144. 73144.79146.08112.85155.12156.98148.03152.44154.09159.80147. 02$31.9032.4734.0339.3441.4946.3646.3250.0055.0360.1162.3664.1470.9374.3076.3378.7482.1288.4094.24101.50106.43108.84112.94115.87118.40121.80130.80126. 78133. 62130. 09129.93129.43132.16131.10129.77131. 54128.23133. 04132. 76131.94139.91135.12132.75135.83137.54134.111 For coverage <strong>of</strong> series, see footnote 1, Table B-26.2 Prior to April 1945, data relate to all employees except executives; for April 1945-May 1949, mainly toemployees subject to <strong>the</strong> Fair Labor Standards Act; and beginning June 1949, to nonsupervisory employeesonly.3 Nine-month average, April through December, because <strong>of</strong> new series started in April 1945.4 Beginning 1964, data include eating and drinking places. Comparable figure excluding eating anddrinking places is $69.94 for 1964.NOTE.—See Note, Table B-25.Data are for production workers in manufacturing and mining, for construction workers in contract construction,and for nonsupervisory employees in o<strong>the</strong>r industries (except as noted). Data are for payperiod which includes <strong>the</strong> 12th <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> month.Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1959.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics.246


TABLE B-29.—Average weekly hours and hourly earnings, gross and excluding overtime, inmanufacturing industries, 7939-66All manufacturing industriesDurable goods manufacturingindustriesNondurable goods manufacturingindustriesAverageweeklyhoursAverage hourlyearningsAverageweeklyhoursAveragehourlyearningsAverageweeklyhoursAveragehourlyearningsYear or monthExcluding)ver-;imeGrossExcludingovertimeExcludinginter-andovertimtryshiftindus-(1957-" 100)GrossExcludingGrossovertimeExcludingGrossovertimeExcludingGrossovertimeExcludingovertime193937.710.62732.237.9&0.69137.4$0.571194019411942194319441945194619471948194938.140.643.145.045.243.540.340.40.0.655.726.851.9571.0111.0161.0751.2171.3281.378$0,691.793.881.9332 .9491.0351.181.291.34133.4137.5140.8143.7145.5150.457.863.66.139.242.045.046.546.544.040.440. c40.439.4.716.799 0.762.872.9661.0191.0311.111.9371.0481.1051.1.1441.2781.1.4531.241.351.4237.038.940.342.543.142.340.540.239.638.9.590627 $0.613.709 684.787 748.844 798.886 2.841.995 .9621.145 1.111.250 1.211.295 1.26195019511952195319541955195619571958195940.540.640.740.539.640.40.439.839.40.337.637.537.237.6.440.56.65.74..78.86.952.052.112.191.391.511.591.681.731.791.891.992.052.1273.677.481.684.86.991.596.2100.2103.541.141.541.41.40.141,41.040.39.540.738.037.937.638.01.5191.651.751.861.901.992.082.192.262.361.461.591.681.791.841.912.012.122.212.2839.739.539.739.639.039.939.639.238.837.237.036.637.0.34;.44.515862677785911.311.401.461.531.581.621.721.801.621.92I960....1961....19621963196419651966 P.-39.840.440.540.741.24137.337.437.37.37.37.637.-2.262.322.392.462.532.612.712.202.252.312.372.442.502.59106.6109.6112.3115.21180121.0124.840.140.340.941.41.42.042.37.738.038.138.38.138.137.82.432.492.562.632.712.792.892.362.422.482.542.602.672.7539.339.639.639.40.140.236.736.836.936.936.836.936.82.052.112.172.222.292.362.452.052.092.152.212.272.351965: JanFebMarAprMayJune37J37.37.37.37.37.2.582.592.592.602.612.612.482.492.492.502.502.50119.120. C120.120.4120.120.841.41.42.41.42.42.38.238.138.338.238.238.22.762.772.782.782.792.792.652.652.662.662.662.6739.739.840.039.440.040.236.936.937.036.736.937.02.332.332.342.342.352.352.252.252.252.262.262.27July.Aug.Sept.Oct..Nov.Dec.37.37.37.37.37.37.2.612.592.632.642.652.662.512.492.512.522.532.54120.120.'121.'121..122.,122.41.41.41.42.42.42.38.037.937.737.937.938.22.792.772.812.822.832.842.672.652.682.682.692.7040.240.340.240.240.340.437.137.136.36.836.37.2.362.362.382.382.392.402.282.272.292.282.292.311966: Jan...Feb..Mar..May".'June.37.37.37.37.37.37.2.672.672.6S2.702.702.712.562.562.562.582.582.58123.123.123.124.124.124.42.42.42.42.42.42.38. 2.8538. C 2.8638.0 2.8637.9 2.8837.9 2.8837.9 2.882.722.722.722.742.742.7439.840.240.239.940.340.536.36.36.636.37.2.402.412.412.432.442.452.312.312.322.332.342.34JulyAugSeptOctNov*Dec*37.37.37.37.37.37.2.712.702.742.752.762.7'2.592.572.612.622.632.64124.124.125.126.126.41.42.42.42.42.42.37.537.737.37.37.38.2.882.872.932.942.942.952.742.732.782.792.802.8140.340.40.340.40.240.36.37.36.36.36.2.462.452.472.482.492.502.352.342.362.372.382.401 Annual average not available; April used.2 Eleven-month average; August 1945 excluded because <strong>of</strong> VJ Day holiday period.NOTE.—See Note, Table B-25.Data relate to production workers and are for pay period which includes <strong>the</strong> 12th <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> month.See Table B-26 for seasonally adjusted average gross weekly hours.Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1959.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics.247


TABLE B-30.—Average weekly earnings, gross and spendable, in manufacturing industries,in current and 1957-59 prices, 1939-66Year or monthAverage gross weeklyearningsAverage spendable weekly earnings 'Worker with nodependentsWorker with threedependentsCurrentprices1957-59prices 2Currentprices1957-59prices 2Currentprices1957-59prices 219391940194119421943194419451946194719481949195019511952 . . .1953195419551956195719581959I960196119621963196419651966 P1965: Jan _ _FebMarApr __ _ .MayJune - - _ .$23.6424.9629.4836.6843.0745.7044.2043.3249.1753.1253.8858.3263.3467.1670.4770.4975.7078.7881.5982.7188.2689.7292.3496.5699.63102.97107. 53112.19105. 52106.19106.71105.82107. 53107. 79$48.8451.1557.4764.5871.4374.5570.4963.7163.2063.3964.9269.5969.9972.6175.6175.3181.1483.1983.2682.1486.9687.0288.6291.6193.3795.2597.8499.2096.9097.5197.9096.8298.1197.90$23.3724.4627.9631.8035.9537.9936.8237.3142.1046.5747.2150.2652.9755.0457.5958.4562.5164.9266.9367.8271.8972.5774.6077.8679.8284.4089.0891.4587.4788.0088.4287.7189.0889.29$48.2950.1254.5055.9959.6261.9758.7254.8754.1155.5756.8859.9858.5359.5061.7962.4567.0068.5568.3067.3570.8370.3971.5973.8774.8178.0881.0680.8680.3280.8181.1280.2581.2881.10$23.4024.7129.1936.3141.3343.7642.5942.7947.5852.3152.9556.3660.1862.9865.6065.6569.7972.2574.3175.2379.4080.1182.1885.5387.5892.1896.7899.3395.0995.6596.0995.3496.7896.99$48.3550 6456.9063 9368 5471.3967.9362 9361.1662 4263.8067.2666 5068.0970.3970.1474 8076.2975 8374.7178.2377.7078 8781.1582.0885.2788.0687.8287.3287.8388.1687.2388.3088.09July. . . _ .AugSeptOctNovDec107.01106.45107.83109.03109.71110.9297.1196.7797.8598.7699.2099.9388.6688.2189.3290.2890.8391.8080.4580.1981.0581.7882.1282.7096.3495.8797.0398.0498.6199.6287.4287.1588.0588.8089.1689.751966- JanFebMarAprMayJune. _ _ .110.00110. 27110.95111. 24112.05112.7499.1098.8199.0698.8899.5199.8689.7990.0090.5190.7391.3591.8780.8980.6580.8180.6581.1381.3797.5897.8098.3498.5799.2299.7787.9187.6387.8087.6288.1288.37JulyAugSeptOct .Nov* . .Dec p111.11111. 78113.71113.85113.99114.6898.0798.2299.6699.4399.4799.9890.6391.1492.6192.7292.8293.3579.9980.0981.1780.9880.9981.3998.4799.00100.54100.65100.76101.3186.9186.9988.1287.9087.9288.331 Average gross weekly earnings less social security and income taxes.2 Earnings in current prices divided by <strong>the</strong> consumer price index on a 1957-59 base.NOTE.—See Note, Table B-25.Data relate to production workers and are for pay period which includes <strong>the</strong> 12th <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> month.Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1959.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics.248


TABLE B-31.—Indexes <strong>of</strong> output per man-hour and related data, private economy, 7947-66[1957-59=100]YearOutput per man-hourTotalprivateFarm NonfarmTotalprivateOutput iFarm NonfarmEstablishment basis 3Man-hours 2Totalprivate Farm Nonfarm1947...1948...1949-1950...1951-1952...1953...1954...1955...1956-.1957...1958...1959.-.I960...1961-1962...1963..1964..1965-1966 P.69.172.174.480.582.984.488.090.094.094.196.999.8103.4105.0108.5113.6117.6122.1125.5129.049.858.056.564.464.770.379.683.784.488.093.3103.0104.8110.7119.4122.2133.1133.7148.8155.874.376.679.684.686.487.189.791.695.795.297.299.7103.1104.4107.3112.2115.6119.9122.4125.367.670.870.677.982.884.889.187.995.497.298.697.3104.1106.6108.6116.0120.8127.5135.3142.582.191.888.993.788.991.896.698.6101.0100.598.1100.5101.9105.8107.2106.8110.1106.3115.0109.266.869.869.777.082.584.588.887.495.197.198.697.2104.2106.7108.7116.5121.4128.6136.4144.397.898.294.996.899.9100.5101.397.7101.5103.3101.897.5100.7101.5100.1102.1102.7104.4107.8110.5164.8158.4157.3145.6137.5130.6121.4117.8119.6114.2105.197.697.295.689.887.482.779.577.370.189.991.187.691.095.597.099.095.499.4102.0101.497.5101.1102.2101.3103.8105.0107.3111.4115.2Labor force basis 41947.1948.194919501951.19521953195467.970.271.978.582.184.588.490.849.858.056.164.164.369.979.183.372.974.576.882.485.787.590.492.867.670.870.677.982.884.889.187.982.191.888.993.788.991.896.698.666.869.869.777.082.584.588.887.499.6100.898.299.2100.9100.4100.896.8164.8158.2158.6146.2138.3131.3122.1118.391.693.790.896.396.698.294.219551956.1957-1958-1959-1960-1961-1962-1963-1964-196594.794.697.299.4103.4104.5107.3113.0116.7120.7124.2128.484.087.593.3103.1104.7110.7119.9122.3133.5134.0149.0155.696.795.997.799.2103.1103.8105.9111.4114.4118.2120.9124.395.497.298.697.3104.1106.6108.6116.0120.8127.5135.3142.5101.0100.598.1100.5101.9105.8107.2106.8110.1106.3115.0109.295.197.198.697.2104.2106.7108.7116.5121.4128.6136.4144.3100.7102.7101.497.9100.7102.0101.2102.7103.5105.6108.9111.0120.3114.9105.297.597.395.689.487.382.579.377.270.298.3101.2100.998.0101.1102.8102.6104.6106.1108.8112.8116.11 Output refers to gross national product in 1958 prices.2 Hours worked by all persons in private industry engaged in production, including man-hours <strong>of</strong> proprietorsand unpaid family workers.3 Man-hours estimates based primarily on establishment data.4 Man-hours estimates based primarily on labor force data.NOTE.—For information on sources, methodology, trends, and underlying factors influencing <strong>the</strong> measures,see Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics, Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Bulletin No. 1249, Trends in Output per Man-Hour in <strong>the</strong> Private Economy, 1909-58, December 1959.Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics.249


PRODUCTION AND BUSINESS ACTIVITYTABLE B—32.—Industrial production indexes, major industry divisions, 1929—66[1957-59 = 100]Year or month1929.19301931.1932.1933.1934.1935.1936.1937.19381939.1940.1941.1942.1943.1944.19451946.19471948.1949.19501951.1952.19531954.1955195619571958195919601961196219631964196519661965: Jan.Feb.MarApr.MayJuneJuly.Aug.Sept.Oct.NovDec_1966: Jan.Feb.MarAprMayJuneJuly.Aug.SeptOct.Nov.DecTotalindustrialproduction38.432.026.520.724.426.630.736.339.731.438.343.956.469.382.981.770.559.565.768.464.774.981.384.391.385.896.699.9100.793.7105.6108.7109.7118.3124.3132.3143.4156.3ManufacturingTotal138.8139.6140.9141.0141.8143.1144.3144.9144.1145.5146.7149.0150.6152. 4153.7153.9155.3156.5157.2158.0157.7158.8158.6158.738.631.725.919.923.726.030.636.439.730.537.958.373.188.786.373.060.066.468.965.175.881.985.292.786.397.3100.2100.893.2106.0108.9109.6118.7124.9133.1145.0158.7DurableNondurable140.3141.3142.5142.5143.3144.6146.0146.4145.8147.0148.6151.0152.9154.7155.9156.6157.6158.9159.4160.1160.0161.4161.0161.038.228.419.511.915.518.824.131.235.222.631.440.057.779.9102.9100.978.254.764.367.060.974.183.588.599.988.4101.9104.0104.090.3105.6108.5107.0117.9124.5133.5148.4165.138.334.832.828.932.833.837.441.644.139.144.947.357.663.770.768.265.664.867.269.568.376.078.580.083.683.691.695.496.796.8106.5109.5112.9119.8125.3132.6140.8150.6Seasonally adjusted142.1143.5145.1145.6147.0148.4150.4150.5149.2150.8151.8155.2158.1160.7161.9162.9164.2165.4166.1167.1167.3169.1167.6167.3Mining54.2.47.040.333.638.540.343.750.356.749.053.860.164.867.069.074.273.072.279.984.074.583.291.390.592.990.299.2104.8104.695.699.7101.6102.6105.0107.9111.5114.8120.2Utilities138.1138.6139.3138.6138.7139.9140.4141.4141.5142.3144.5145.7146.4147.3148.5148.7149.4150.7151.3151.3150.9151.7152.8153.2112.9112.2112.8113.1114.2115.2115.9116.7112.5116.4116.4118.3117.3117.7120.0115.6120.7122.0122.0122.1121.0121.4120.8122.8Source: Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System.250


TABLE B-33.—Industrial production indexes, market groupings, 1947-66[1957-59=100]Year or monthTotalindustrialproductionFinal productsTotalConsumer goods *TotalAutomotiveproductsHomegoodsEquipmentTotal,includingdefenseBusinessMaterialsTotalDurablegoodsNondurablegoods194719481949195019511952195319541955195619571958195919601961196219631964196519661965: Jan..Feb..Mar-Apr..May.June.July.Aug.Sept.Oct..Nov.Dec.1966: Jan...Feb..Mar..Apr..May.June-July..Aug..Sept..Oct...Nov..Dec65.768.464.774.981.384.391.385.896.699.9100.793.7105.6108.7109.7118.3124.3132.3143.4156.364.266.664.572.878.684.389.985.793.998.199.494.8105.7109.9111.2119.7124.9131.8142.5155.467.169.268.878.677.879.585.084.393.395.597.096.4106.6111.0112.6119.7125.2131.7140.3147.469,472.672.090.680.172.191.385.0118.397.8105.286.7108.1123.2111.8131.1141.2145.1167.2163.268.871.766.391.478.778.890.286.097.3100.996.692.8110.7110.8112.2122.2129.6141.1154.8168.855.458.352.056.478.494.1100.595.0103.7104.691.3104.1107.6108.3119.6124.2132.0147.0172.769.972.663.568.083.194.196.685.191.9104.7105.389.8104.9110.2110.1122.1128.3139.1156. 7181.267.070.264.876.983.884.392.685.999.0101.6101.992.7105.4107.6108.4117.0123.7132.8144.2157.168.271.064.279.587.888.9100.788.4104.7105.3104.890.0105.1106.6104.8114.1121.2131.2144.3157.4Seasonally adjusted138.8139.6140.9141.0141.8143.1144.3144.9144.1145.5146.7149.0150.6152.4153.7153.9155.3156.5157.2158.0157.7158.8158.6158.7138.3138.8140.2139.5140.2141.3142.1143.0143.7145.7148.0148.9150.3152.1152.5152.9153.7154.9155.3156.4156.3158.4158.4159.0138.2138.4140.0138.5138.6139.5139.8140.5141.3141.9143.7144.2144.6146.1146.2146.4146.2147.1146.5147.1146.5148.9148.4148.7165.4164.2171.5166.6167.3167.5167.1166.7165.2168.0168.5169.1168.1167.9170.0168.4160.7162.3154.5146.4150.7168.5163.3164149.7151.2153.0151.0152.6152.3153.3151.4155.3158.8159.7165.8166.8165.7164.1168.4169.9168.3168.0168.9166.0170.1168.9138.5139.7140.7141.6143.8145.2147.6148.5149.0153.9157.3159.0162.6164.8166.2166.9169.8171.4174.4176.4177.4179.0180.1181.2148.0149.5150.4151.2153.5154.9157.1158.0159.0163.8167.2169.1171.9174.0175.4175.9178.3180.0182.7184.4185.7187.4187.9189139.4140.2141.4142.5143.5145.2146.4146.5144.9145.3146.1148.8150.9152.6154.4154.5157.1158.0158.8159.6159.2159.6158.8158.4138.5139.9142.6142.8144.8146.5148.5147.3144.3144.3143.6147.3149.9152.6155.6156.7157.7159.3159.1160.1159.8159.7158.715664.968.264.273.378.879.084.183.393.097.798.995.4105.7108.7112.2120.0126.3134.4144.1156.8139.7139.9139.6141.5142.1143.8144.7145.6145.4147.1148.6150.4151.0152.1153.1152.3156.5158.0158.6159.1158.6159.6159.51611 Also includes apparel and consumer staples, not shown separately.Source: Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System.251


TABLE B-34.—Industrial production indexes, selected manufactures, 1947-66[1957-59=100]Year ormonth1947..1948-.1949..1950..1951..1952..1953.1954.1955.1956-1957.1958.1959.1960.1961.1962.1963-1964.1965-._1966 P..1965: Jan....Feb.-Mar..Apr...May-June...July..Aug__Sept-.Oct.._Nov--Dec-_1966: Jan...Feb...Mar..May IIJune..July..Aug__Sept.-Oct...Nov_.Dec v_Durable manufacturesPrimarymetals90.794.379.4108.799.3112.591.3118.4116.4112.287.5100.4101.398.9104.6113.3129.1137.6142.8Fabricatedmetalproducts75.977.285.491.289.0100.390.298.398.8101.592.9105.5107.6106.5117.1123.4132.7147.8163.0Maihinery65.366.559.072.783.092.1100.587.796.5107.1104.288.8107.1110.8110.4123.5129.2141.4160.5183.9Transportationequipment42.946.947.156.462.973.191.783.8102.097.4106.489.5104.0108.2103.6118.3127.0130.7149.2168.1Instrumentsand relatedproducts53.755.249.257.365.778.185.382.988.795.498.092.1109.9116.5115.8123.0130.2136.4151.4176.3Clay,glass,andlumberFurnitureandmiscellaneous75.879.772.387.792.089.392.7100.7102.097.594.1108.5105.7104.5109.3114.4121.1127.6133.0Textile,apparel,andlea<strong>the</strong>rproducts73.577.471.683.780.282.489.786.897.9101.097.693.3109.0113.3114.1124.5129.1138.4151.8165.1Nondurable manufacturesPaperandprintingSeasonally adjusted139.6139.5140.4142.5142.9144.5149.6146.6132.6125. 0120.6126.5131.9138.3141.8142.4146.5148.0148.6148.7146.4144.6139.4137140.3145.0144.8147.1145.7146.0148.0147.5146.7150.9153.6156.3157.7161.6161.7161.4162.9161.8162.1161.4163.0164.2164.5167151.6153.6155.4155.5157.2159.1161.0161.6164.3166.4168.3171.0174.5176.4176.1178.6180.6182.8186.6189.6188.8191.1189.8189141.2141.0144.6144.7147.5148.9149.6151.2149.8154.9157.2160.4163.0164.1166.1165.9165.8167.1166.0166.0168.3174.8172.6172143.4143.8145.4146.9147.0149.8152.1152.6155.7158.0159.0162.2166.8169.4171.9174.6176.4176.5177.0177.4179.5181.8181.3183123.2124.8125.9124.1126.1126.8127.7127.8128.4130.1130.3135.0136.2136.4138.0137.8133.3134.4131.7129.8129.8128.1126.7126145.2147.6148.4149.1150.1150.3150.5151.9152.7155.1157.8160.9158.4161.6162.9163.5166.7167.0163.5167.1165.9165.3166.216781.084.580.689.187.489.590.786.995.598.096.995.0108.1107.5108.4115.1118.5125.2135.8141.466.769.469.376.779.477.782.685.092.597.197.897.0105.2109.0112.4116.7120.1127.5135.3146.5Chemical,petroleum,andrubberproducts133.1133.8134.4134.2134.9135.4134.6134.7136.5137.3138.7140.2138.6139.8141.1142.6142.0143.4141.6140.1140.2141.0141.114147.550.849.460.767.469.975.274.791.495.695.5108.9113.9118.9131.2141.8152.5164.6181.7Foods,beverages,andtobacco80.780.080.883.685.487.388.289.893.196.696.799.4103.9106.6110.2113.3116.8120.8123.4127.6132.1132.0133.0133.3134.2134.8135.9136.9136.0136.4139.2140.6142.1142.7144.2143.5146.6148.3149.6148.6147.2147.9148.3149159.1160.9162.0160.3160.9163.2164.6166.4166.3167.9170.6172.8174.6175.1176.6177.3179.3180.1182.0182.4182.8185.5187.1188124.1123.5123.7123.0121.6122.5122.7123.1123.4123.3125.1124.8125.7126.8127.4126.9125.5126.8127.2128.5127.9126.7128.6128Source: Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System.252


TABLE B-35.—Manufacturing capacity, output, and utilization rate, 1948—6619481949PeriodCapacity i7983Output(1957-59=100)6965Utilizationrate(percent) 2 87791950195119521953195485899499104768285938689939094831955195619571958195910911412112613097100101931069088847482I9601961196219631964135139144149155109110119125133817982848619651966 P..1631741451598991Seasonally adjusted1961' I II IIIIV138139140141103108112115757880821962- I II IIIrv1963: I IIIIIrv1964: I II IIIIV1421431451461471491501511531541561571171191201201211251261271291331351368283838282848484858687871965: IIIIIIIV159162165167141144146149898989891966: IIIIIIIV p170173176179155158160161919191901 For description and source <strong>of</strong> data see "A Revised Index <strong>of</strong> Manufacturing Capacity," Federal ReserveBulletin, November 1966, pp. 1605-1615, Frank de Leeuw, Frank E. Hopkins, and Michael D. Sherman.See also McGraw-Hill surveys on "Business Plans for New Plants and Equipment" for data on capacityand operating rates.2 Output as percent <strong>of</strong> capacity; based on unrounded data.Source: Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System (output) and sources in footnote 1 (capacityand utilization rate).240-782 0—67-253


TABLE B-36.—New construction activity, 1929-66[Value put in place, millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Private constructionPublic constructionYear or monthTotalnewconstructionTotalResidentialbuilding(nonfarm)Total iNewhousingunitsNonresidential building ando<strong>the</strong>r constructionTotalO<strong>the</strong>r 3TotalCommercialsIndustrialFederalStateandfunds*localfunds192910,7938,3073,6253,0404,6821,1359492,5982,4862352,251193019311932193319341935193619371938 .19398,7416,4273,5382,8793,7204,2326,4976,9996,9808,1985,8833,7681,6761,2311,5091,9992,9813,9033,5604,3892,0751,5656304706251,0101,5651,8751,9902,6801,5701,3204852903807101,2101,4751,6202,2703,8082,2031,0467618849891,4162,0281,5701,709454223130173211290387285292532221741761911582664922322542,3831,5287494555206208601,1491,0531,1632,8582,6591,8621,6482,2112,2333,5163,0963,4203,8093135064448021,3471,3812,3631,8932,0372,1362,5452,1531,4188468648521,1531,2031,3831,673194019411942194319441945194611,95714,0758,3015,2595,80912,6275,0546,2063,4151,9792,1863,41110,3962,9853,5101,7158858151,2764, 7522,5603,0401,4407105707203,3002,0692,6961,7001,0941,3712,1355,64434840915533562031,1534428013461562086421,2791,4861,1999051,1071,2902,8023,6285,75110,6606,3223,0732,3982,2312,1284,4489,7885,8772,6311,8361,1091,5001,3038724454425621,122New series 8194619471948194919501951195219531954195519561957195819591960196119621963New series 619621963196419651966 »14,30820,04126, 07826, 72233, 57535,43539,13641,38046, 51947, 60149,13950,15355,30553,94155,44759, 57662, 75559,66762,96866, 22171,93074,60312,07716,72221,37420,45326,70926,18026,04927, 89429,66834,80434,86935,08034,69639,23538,07838,29941,70743,85941,79843,64245,91449,99950,6286,2479,85013,12812,42818,12615,88115,80316, 59418,18721,87720,17819,00619, 78924, 25121,70621,68024,29225,84324,29225,84326,50726, 68924,6164,7957,76510,50610,04315, 55113, 20712,85113,41114,93118,24216,14314,73615,44519,23316,41016,18918,63820,06418,63820,06420,61220,76518,7565,8306,8728,2468,0258,58310,29910,24611,30011,48112,92714, 69116,07414,90714,98416,37216,61917, 41518, 01617,50617,79919, 40723, 31026,0121,1539571,3971,1821,4151,4981,1371,7912,2123,2183,6313,5643,5893,9304,1804,6744,9555,2005,1444,9955,4066,7041,6891,7021,3979721,0622,1172,3202,2292,0302,3993,0843, 5572,3822,1062,8512,7802,9492,9622,8422,9063,5725,08613,6902,9884,2135,4525,8716,1066,6846,7897,2807,2397,3107,9768,9539,3419,1659,5119,8549,5209,89810, 42911, 52012,3222,2313,3194,7046,2699,25510, 77911,24211, 71211,71512, 73214,05915,45716,07015,86317,14817,86918,89617,86919, 32620, 30721,93123,9751,1091,2491,5941,9492,0783,4454,7354,8394,1033,5083,5834,2435,4936,4355,8896,3056,4697,1207,1207,3117,0681,1222,0703,1104,3204,7885,8106,0446,4037,6098,2079,1499,8169,9649,6359,97410,84311, 40G11, 77611, 40012,20612,99614,863See footnotes at end <strong>of</strong> table.254


TABLE B-36.—New construction activity, 7929-66-—Continued[Value put in place, millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Private constructionPublic constructionYear or monthTotalResidentialbuilding(nonfarm>Total iTotalnewconstructionNewhousingunitsNonresidential building ando<strong>the</strong>r constructionTotalO<strong>the</strong>r 3TotalCommercialIndustrialFederalfunds 4StateandlocalfundsSeasonally adjusted annual rates1965: Jan..Feb..Mar.Apr..May.June.July.Aug.Sept.Oct..Nov.Dec.1966: Jan..Feb.Mar.Apr.MayJune.July.Aug.Sept.Oct..Nov.Dec i68,82370,36171,17071,41171,97371,75670,35870,86372,83072,68774,03976, 44377,62278,92079,49978,57876,13575,89473,82773,50973,62770,30971,09470,37347,69748,92749,41449,71750,13250,31749,12249,22250,16750,08451,20953, 44553,28554,29055,06654, 34752,28452,10850,06149,66849,72546,75447,09146,56226,67626,71326,60226,67527, 07027,22426,98326,62126, 41326, 34326,24326, 68427,46027,46327, 27927, 43727, 02326,15625,11523,92723,10022,01220,77720,32020,84520,86620,73520,76221, 07721, 20320,99020,65720, 49120,41620,34020,78021,57421,55421,40021,57821,14620,24921, 02122,21422,81223,04223,06223, 09322,13922,60123,75423,74124,96626,76125,82526,82727,78726,91025,26125,95219,193 24,94618, 037 25.74117, 293 26,62516,220 24.74214,971 26,31414,536 26,2426,4156,5996,6006,7096,0916,199'5,8826,2396,9777,0567,7068,0177,8467,2947,6727,0976,1266,3436,2806,4827,0546,6087,0283,7124,4784,9694,7755,4165,4264,9074,9735,3215,0685,2916,2505,9876,6297,0737,1756,8567,5487,1637,1646,9136,2236,69810,894 21,12611,137 21,43411,243 21,75611,558 21,69411,555 21,84111,468 21,43911,350 21,23611,389 21,64111,456 22,66311,617 22,60311,969 22,83012, 494 22,99811,992 24,33712,904 24,63013,042 24,43312,638 24,23112,279 23,85112,061 23,78611,503 23,76612, 095 23,84112,658 23,90211,911 23,55512,588 24,00312,516 23,81112 Total includes additions and alterations and nonhousekeeping units not shown separately.Office buildings, warehouses, stores, restaurants, and garages.4 3 Farm, institutional, public utilities, and all o<strong>the</strong>r private.Includes Federal grants-in-aid for State and locally owned projects.5 New series in 1946 reflects differences due to <strong>the</strong> new higher level series <strong>of</strong> housing starts and farm constructionexpenditures and <strong>the</strong> reduced level value in place series for public utilities. See Construction<strong>Report</strong> 6 CSO-61 {Supplement) for a description <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> differences.New series differs from old in that it reflects differences in 1962 due to <strong>the</strong> introduction <strong>of</strong> new series forprivate nonresidential buildings and differences in 1963 due to <strong>the</strong> introduction <strong>of</strong> new series for State andlocally owned public construction. See Construction <strong>Report</strong> C30-65S for a description <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> differences.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1959.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Census.255


TABLE B-37.—New housing starts and applications for financing, 1929—66[Thousands <strong>of</strong> units]Year ormonth192919301931193219331934193519361937 . -.193819391940 —1941194219431944New series1945.1946194719481949195019511952195319541955195619571958...19591960196119621963196419651966 »Housing startsPrivate andpublicTotal(farmandnonfarm)1,553.51,296.01,365.01,492.41,641.01,590.71,542.71,252.3Nonfarm509.0330.0254.0134.093.0126.0221.0319.0336.0406.0515.0602.6706.1356.0191.0141.8326.11,023.21,268.51,362.11,466.11,951.91,491.01,503.91,437.61,550.51,646.01,349.11,223.91,382.01,531.31,274.01,336.81,468. 71,613.41,563.71,520.41,229.0PrivateTotal(includingfarm)1,516.81,252.11,313.01,462.71,609.21,557.41,505.01,220.5NonfarmTotal i509.0330.0254.0134.093.0126.0215.7304.2332.4399.3458.4529.6619.5301.2183.7138.7324.91,015.21,265.11,344.01,429.81,908.11,419.81,445.41,402.11,531.81,626.61,324.91,174.81,314.21,494.61,230.11,284.81,439.01,581.71,530.41,482.71,197.2Onefamily316.0227.0187.0118.076.0109.0182.2238.5265.8316.4373.0447.6533.2252.3136.3114.61,212.1972.7946.2967.8993.2944.5940.0772.9Twoormorefamilies193.0103.067.016.017.017.033.565.766.682.985.482.086.348.947.424.1~~282~5257.4338.6471.2588.5585.9542.7424.3PrivateTotal(includingfarm)1,516.81,252.11,313.01,462.71,609.21,557.41,505.01,220.5NonfarmTotal509.0330.0254.0134.093.0126.0215.7304.2332.4399.3458.4529.6619.5301.2183.7138.7324.91,015.21,265.11,344.01,429.81,908.11,419.81,445.41,402.11,531.81,626.61,324.91,174.81,314.21,494.61,230.11,284.81,439.01,581.71,530.41,482.71,197.2GovernmenthomeprogramsFHA13.248.857.0106.8144.7176.6217.1160.2126.183.638.967.1178.3216.4252.6328.2186.9229.1216.5250.9268.7183.4150.1270.3307.0225.7198.8197.3166.2154.0159.9129.1VA::::::9L8160.371.190.8191.2148.6141.3156.5307.0392.9270.7128.3102.1109.374.683.377.871.059.252.540.5Newprivatehousingunitsauthorized2-------1,208.3998.01,064.21,186.61,334.71,285.81,240.6966.4Proposedhome construction3ApplicationsforFHAcommitments


TABLE B-37.—New housing starts and applications for financing, 1929-66—Continued[Thousands <strong>of</strong> units]Year ormonthPrivate andpublicTotal(farmandnonfarm)NonfarmTotal(includingfarm)Total iHousing startsPrivateNonfarmOnefamilyTwoormorelies"Total(includingfarm)PrivateTotalNonfarmGovernmenthomeprogramsFHAVANewprivatehousingunitsauthorized2Proposedhome construction3plicationsforFHAcommentsRequestsforVAappraisalsSeasonally adjusted annual rates1965: Jan..Feb..Mar..Apr..May-June .July..Aug..SeptOct.VNov.-Dec.1966: Jan__Feb..Mar..Apr..May.June.July..Aug-SeptOct..Nov*.Dec*.85.687.9124.9154.9162.1162.3143.9138.0125.9135.7118.3103.287.381.0130.9149.2139.3130.7104.8107.395.282.877.166.584.287.1123.0152.8159.8159.7141.6136.2124.3133.0117.1101.686.379.5128.7146.9136.1128.3103.1105.293.080.675.865.381.485.4120.7152.2157.5155.5141.3134.7124.3133.6116.1102.384.678.2126.3147.1135.4127.5104.0105.492.480.274.864.480.184.7118.8150.1155.2152.8139.0132.8122.7130.9114.9100.883.776.7124.1144.8132.2125.1102.3103.390.278.173.563.250.450.774.897.799.997.091.886.578.484.470.258.347.245.378.793.084.881.469.769.160.153.049.241.629.734.044.052.455.355.847.246.344.346.544.742.536.531.445.451.847.443.732.634.230.125.124.321.61,442L,4821,489: L,5521,516L,566] L,47331,427] L,4471,4091,453 1,4361,411 1,3801,547 1,5311,769 1,7351,6111,3741,5691,5021,3181,2851,0881,1071,0758481,0071,1021,4171,4681,465L,532L,5011,5391,5851,3491,5381,4811,2871,2611,0681,0841,0508269881,07916816416314615515415114816016717318918117718715112812111711396941071056761565054545248474954485340453738444235373840421,2731,2261,2451,2041,2431,2451,2341,2281,1801,2441,2801,2921,2551,1971,2681,1851,098954921844733714715772196194175187180154165186189192222219214179160168133127124119151122135203107116106100113100959597941001058972921119890991041021191031041 Military housing starts, including those financed with mortgages insured by FHA under Section 803<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> National Housing Act, are included in publicly financed starts but excluded from total private startsand from FHA starts.2 Data beginning 1963 cover approximately 12,000 permit-issuing places. Data for 1959-62 are based onreports from approximately 10,000 places. In 1963, <strong>the</strong> additional 2,000 permit-issuing places accountedfor almost 50,000 new privately owned housing unit authorizations.3 Units in mortgage applications or appraisal requests for new home construction.* FHA program approved in June 1934; all 1934 activity included in 1935.5 Monthly estimates for September 1945-May 1950 were prepared by Housing and Home Finance Agency.NOTE.—Census series beginning 1945 include Alaska and Hawaii. FHA and VA series include Alaska,Hawaii, and Puerto Rico for all periods.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce (Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Census), Department <strong>of</strong> Housing and Urban Development, Federal Housing Administration (FHA), and Veterans Administration (VA), except as noted257


TABLE B-38.—Business expenditures for new plant and equipment, 1939 and 1945-67[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year or quarterTotal iTotalManufacturingDurablegoodsNondurablegoodsMiningTransportationRailroadO<strong>the</strong>rPublicutilitiesCommercialando<strong>the</strong>r 21939 _ _19451946 _ __194719481949 - -195019511952 - -19531954195519561957 _1958.1959 - -- .1960196119621963196419651966 35.518.6914.8520.6122.0619.2820.6025.6426.4928.3226.8328.7035.0836.9630.5332.5435.6834.3737.3139.2244.9051.9660.561.943.986.798.709.137.157.4910.8511.6311.9111.0411.4414.9515.9611.4312.0714.4813.6814.6815.6918.5822.4527.010.761.593.113.413.482.593.145.175.615.655.095.447.628.025.475.777.186.277.037.859.4311.4014.041.192.393.685.305.654.564.365.686.026.265.956.007.337.945.966.297.307.407.657.849.1611.0512.970.33.38.43.69.88.79.71.93.98.99.98.961.241.24.94.99.99.981.081.041.191.301.470.28.55.58.891.321.351.111.471.401.31.85.921.231.40.75.921.03.67.851.101.411.731.940.36.57.921.301.28.891.211.491.501.561.511.601.711.771.502.021.941.852.071.922.382.813.480.52.50.791.542.543.123.313.663.894.554.224.314.906.206.095.675.685.525.485.656.226.948.312 082 705 337 496 905.986.787 247 098.008.239.4711.0510.409.8110.8811.5711.6813.1513.8215.1316.7318.36Seasonally adjusted annual rates1964: IIIIIIIV1965: IIIIIIIV .1966: IIIIIIIV 31967: I 3113_ _42.5543.5045.6547.7549.0050.3552.7555.3558.0060.1061.2562.6063.4564.0517.4017.8018.8520.1520.7521.5523.0024.1525.6026.8027.5527.8027.8528.458.859.009.6010.1510.4010.8011.7512.4513.1513.8514.3514.6514.7015.108.558.809.2010.0010.4010.7011.2511.7012.4512.9513.2013.1513.1513.351.15151.203025.30L.351.40L.551.451,451.501.40L 25.5055,75L.5570951.752.001.852.152.002.302.252.402.602.552.703.003.003.303.503.403.703.6535.605.956.306.306.356.806.856.757.308.258.308.558.159.3014.3514.7515.4015.8015.8516.4017.0017.5517.7017.9518.4519.2519.151 Excludes agriculture.2 Commercial and o<strong>the</strong>r includes trade, service, finance,communications, and construction.3 Estimates based on anticipated capital expenditures reported by business in late October and November1966. The quarterly anticipations include adjustments, when necessary, for systematic tendencies inanticipatory data.NOTE.—Annual total is <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> unadjusted expenditures; it does not necessarily coincide with <strong>the</strong>average <strong>of</strong> seasonally adjusted figures.These figures do not agree precisely with plant and equipment expenditures included in <strong>the</strong> grossnational product estimates <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce. The main difference lies in <strong>the</strong> inclusionin <strong>the</strong> gross national product <strong>of</strong> investment by farmers, pr<strong>of</strong>essionals, institutions, and real estate firms,and <strong>of</strong> certain outlays charged to current account.These series are not available for years prior to 1939 and for 1940 to 1944.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce (Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s) and Securities and ExchangeCommission.258


TABLE B-39.—Sales and inventories in manufacturing and trade, 1947-66[Amounts in millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year or monthTotal manufacturingand tradeInventories2Ratio 3 Sales iManufacturingInventories2 Ratio 3MerchantwholesalersSales i Inventories2Ratio 3 Sales iRetail tradeInventories2Ratio s1947..1948..1949..1950..1951..1952..1953..1954..1955..1956..1957..1958-1959..35,26033,78838,59643,35644,84047,98746,44351,69454,06355,87954,23359,66152,50749,49759,82270,24272,37776,12273,17579,51687,30489,05286,92291,8911.421.531.361.551.581.1.601.471.551.591.601.5015,51317,31616,12618,63421,71422,52924,84323,35526,48027,74028,73627,28030,21925,89728,54326,32131,07839,30641,13643,94841,61245,06950,64251,87150,07052,7071.581.571.751.481.661.781.761.811.621.731.801.841.706,8086,5147,18,5978,7829,0529,89310,51310,47510,25711,4917,9577,7069,2849,88610,21010,63711,67813,26012,73012,73913,8791.131.191.071.161.121.171.181.131.191.231.241.1510,20011,13511,14912,26813,04613,52914,09114,09515,32115,81116,66716,69617,95114,24116,00715,47019,46021,05021,03121,48820,92622,76923,40224,45124,11325,3051.26.39.41.64.52.53.51.43.47.44.43.40I960..1961-1962-1963-1964..1965—1966


TABLE B-40.—Manufacturers' shipments and inventories, 1947—66[Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year or month1947..1948-1949..1950..1951..1952-1953-1954..1955..1956..1957-1958..1959..1960-1961..1962..1963-1964-1965 -1966 3Shipments xInventories 2Durable goods industries Nondurable goods industriesDurabldurableMate-Mate-Non-Total goods goods Total rials Work Finishedindustrietriessup-process goods Total rials Work Fin-indus-Total and inand in ishedsuppliesprocess goodsplies15,51317,31616,12618,63421,71422,52924,84323,35526,48027,74028,73627,28030,21930,79630,88433,30834,77437,12940,27943,9007,5797,1918,84510,49311,31313,34911,82814,07114,71515,23713,57215,54415,81715,53217,18418,07119,23121,02022,9008,819 25,89713,0619738 9,28,543 28543 14,6628,935 26321 26,321 13,0609,789 31,078 V 15,53911,22139, 9,306 20,99111,216 41, 1,136 23,73111,494 43, 3,948 25,87811,527 41,612 23, 7105,069 26,40513; 025 50,642 30,44713,499 51,87131,72813,708 50,070 30,09514,979 53,814 32,36015,352 55,087 32,64616,124 57,753 34,32616,704 60,147 36,02817,898 62,944 38, "~19,258 68,015 42,32421, 000 76,900 49, 3008,9667,8949,19410,41710,6089,84710,58510,28610,23410,57110,87911,68812,94314,50010,7209,72110,75612,31712,83712,29412,95212,78013,22514,12914,85715,93318,10922, 00012,83613,88113,26115,53918,31517,4056,206 18,0706,040 17,9026,348 18,6647,565 20,1958,125 20,1437,749 19,9758,143 20,8689,190 21,4549,088 22,4419,593 23,42710,292 24,11910,791 24,53211, 27225,69112,800 27, 6008,3178,1678,5568,9718,7758,6719,0899,1139,5119,7709,7699,6199,96410,6002,4722,4402,5712,7212,8642,8002,9282,9353,1203,3043,4793,5223,8624,3007,4097,4157,6668,6228,6248,4988,8579,3539,70710,24610,87111,39111,86512,700Seasonally adjusted1965: JanFebMarAprMayJuneJuly.Aug..Sept_Oct..Nov-.Dec-.1966: JanFebMarAprMayJuneJulyAugSeptOctNov PDec*>_._38,885 20,41538,693 20,37440,285 21,28440,044 20,91539, 814 20, 51339,943 20,65241,45240,51840,17340, 54841,40342,62242,66542,70244,12143,54044,07144,12544,32744,20644,09144, 48744, 50321,82021,19120,92421,14621,60622,31622,30722,43323,23822,70822,91522,89823,03122,87422,97123, 45123, 34923,81318,470 63, 213 38,495 11,80218,319 63,382 38; 1,692 11,87619,001 63,708 38,972 12,06819,129 63,999) 39,233 12,40619,301 64,269 I 39,475 12,51219,291 64, t; 625 39,951 12,53719,632 65,394 40,60019,327 65,788 40,81419,249 66, 267 41,30019, 402 66, 642 41,52319,797 67,192 41,86920,306 68, 015 42, 32420,358 88,594 42, 58920,269 69,040 42,88420,883 69,648 43,27320,832 70,346 43,77921,156 71,103 44,27521,227 71,949 45, 00321,296 72,958 45,79021,332 74,110 46,81421,120 74,884 47,56821, 036 75,788 48, 35221,154 76,854 49, 24012,66412,67212,81212,88612,91412,94312,95113,00412,98813,14613,29813,50713, 65313,99714,30914, 46514, 52115,93416,00816,04116,11416,16216,53317,05317,28317,38017, 50217,76318,10918,28518,46818,80719,14119,30219,69320,23520,69820,94921, 44621,95210, 75924,71810,808 24,69010,863 24, 73610, 71324,76610,801 24,79410,881 24,67410; 88324,79410,859 24,97411,108 24,96711,135 25,11911,192 25,32311,272 25,69111,353 26, •,00511,412 26, i, 15611,478 26,37511,492 26,56711,675 26,82811,803 26,94611,902 27,16812,119 27,29612, 310 27,31612, 441 27, 43612,767 27,6149,5859,5419,5579,6609,6759,6089,5379,6459,7669,7699,8279,96410,02810,07210,15310,30910,43910,56210,50610,61510, 57910,54210,6553,5323,5313,5333,5333,5583,6113,5913,6623,7023,8253,8233,8623,8763,8773,9133,9914,0444,0624,1264,1694,2514,26311,60111,61811,64611,57311,56111,45511,66611,66711,49911,52511,67311,86512,10112,20712,32912,34512,39812,34012,60012,55512,56812,64312,6961 Monthly average for year and total for month.2 Book value, seasonally adjusted, end <strong>of</strong> period.3 Where December data not available, data for year calculated on basis <strong>of</strong> no change from November.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1958.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Census.260


TABLE B-41.—Manufacturers* new and unfilled orders, 1947—66[Amounts in millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]New orders *Unfilled orders 2Unfilled orders-shipmentsratio 3Year or monthTotalDurable goodsindustriesTotalTotalMachineryandequipmentNondurablegoodsindustriesDurablegoodsindustriesNondurablegoodsindustriesTotalDurablegoodsindustriesNondurablegoodsindustries1947-1948-1949-15,25617,69215,6148,1269,5668,98134,41530,71724,50628,53226,60120,0185,8834,1164,4881950..1951-1952-1953-1954-20,11023,90723,20323,53322,31310,16512,84112,06112,10510,7432,0841,7709,94511,06611,14211,42811,57043,05569,78575,64961,17848,26636,83865,83572,48058,63745,2506,2173,9503,1692,5413,0163.424.120.961955-1956-1957-1958-1959-27,42327,51426,90130,67914,95415,38114,07313,17015,9512,4992,8702,5662,3542,87812,46913,00213,44113,73114,72860,00467,37553,18348,88254,49456,24163,88050,35245,73950,6543,7633,4952,8313,1433,8403.873.354.274.554.001.121.C4.851960-1961-1962-1963-1964-30,11531,06133,16735,03637,69715,22315,66417,08518,30019,8032,7912,8543,0903,3263,70614,89215,39716,08216,73617,89546,13348,34346,78449,79657,04443,40145,17344,09446,67653,9582,7323,1702,6903,1203,0862.522.442.362.453.012.942.852.96.76.65.66.611965..1966 f41,02345,00021,72824,1004,1404,80019,29520,90066,06879,60062,53476,2003,5343,4002.612.983.16.64.58Seasonally adjusted1965: Jan...Feb..Max..Apr..May..June..39,70439,46940,71241,12040,18140,68921,27121,13021,71422,04320,99221,3103,9583,7994,0244,0784,0694,09118,43318,33918,99819,07719,18919,37957,31758,16058,59559,46359,89760,58854,28055,09255,53156,37456,87557,4543,0373,0683,0643,0893,0223,1342.482.532.462.512.562.583.013.072.983.043.133.150.60.61.59.60.57.60July..Aug..Sept..Oct..Nov.Dec..41,84640,92641,48341,84342,23443,86822,19521,50922,16322,42522,38923,4034,3484,1594,1534,2494,3254,58319,65119,41719,32019,41819,84520,46560,98161,39162,69963,99364,82166,06857,83058,14859,38560,66461,44562,5343,1513,2433,3143,3293,3763,5342.482.572.662.692.652.613.023.123.233.283.233.16.58.62.64.63.62.64: Jan...Feb...Mar..Apr...May..June..43,98644,12945,83345,06445,32145,83323,57823,74124,88824,19724,27624,5934,4504,5844,5874,7884,8454,75320,40820,38820,94520,86721, 04521,24067,38868,81470,52772,04973,29775, 00963,80365,11066,76268,25069,60971,3083,5853,7043,7653,7993,6883,7012.652.712.692.782.792.863.213.283.253.373.403.50.65.68.66.68.64.64July..Aug__sept—Oct.—Nov *.Dec *>_45,62544,84246,31845,24344,17624,37123,51225,27424,24423,14623,8855,0924,8134,9064,8164,6854,68521,25421,33021, 04420,99921,03076,31076,94279,17079,92379,59672,65173,28675,59176,38276,17976,2533,6593,6563,5793,5413,4172.832.892.973.002.983.493.543.643.673.66.61.62.61.601 Monthly average for year and total for month.2 Seasonally adjusted, end <strong>of</strong> period.3 Ratio <strong>of</strong> shipments for period to unfilled orders at end <strong>of</strong> period. Annual figures relate to seasonallyadjusted data for December.* Where December data not available, data for year calculated on basis <strong>of</strong> no change from November.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1958.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Census.26l


PRICESTABLE B-42.—Consumer price indexes, by major groups, 1929-66For city wage earners and clerical workers[1957-59=100]Year or month192919301931193219331934193519361937193819391940194119421943194419451946194719481949195019511952195319541955195619571958195919601961196219631964 ---1965 ._.19661965: Jan..Feb.Mar.Apr.MayJuneJuly.Aug.Sept.Oct..Nov.Dec.1966: Jan..Feb.Mar.Apr-MayJuneJuly.Aug.Sept.Oct..Nov.Dec.Allitems59.758.253.047.645.146.647.848.350.049.148.448.851.356.860.361.362.768.077.883.883.083.890.592.593.293.693.394.798.0100.7101.5103.1104.2105.4106.7108.1109.9113.1108.9108.9109.0109.3109.6110.1110.2110.0110.2110.4110.6111.0111.0111.6112.0112.5112.6112.9113.3113.8114.1114.5114.6114.7Food55.652.943.636.335.339.342.142.544.241.039.940.544.251.957.957.158.466.981.388.284.785.895.497.195.695.494.094.797.8101.9100.3101.4102.6103.6105.1106.4108.8114.2106.6106.6106.9107.3107.9110.1110.9110.1109.7109.7109.7110.6111.4113.1113.9114.0113.5113.9114.3115.8115.6115.6114.8114.8HousingTotal56.357.159.160.159.759.961.464.264.966.467.569.374.579.881.083.288.289.992.393.494.195.598.5100.2101.3103.1103.9104.8106.0107.2108.5111.1108.1108.2108.2108.2108.2108.2108.3108.2108.6109.0109.2109.4109.2109.4109.6110.3110.7111.1111.3111.5111.8112.2112.6113.0Rent85.483.178.770.660.857.056.958.360.962.963.063.264.365.765.765.966.166.568.773.276.479.182.385.790.393.594.896.598.3100.1101.6103.1104.4105.7106.8107.8108.9110.4108.4108.5108.7108.8108.8108.8108.9109.0109.1109.2109.3109.5109.7109.8109.9110.1110.2110. 2110.3110.6110.7111.0111.2111.3Apparelandupkeep55.354.149.243.642.146.146.546.949.349.048.348.851.159.662.266.770.176.989.295.091.390.198.297.296.596.395.997.899.599.8100.6102.2103.0103.6104.8105.7106.8109.6105.6105.8106.0106.3106.8106.9106.1106.4107.2107.8108.1108.1107.3107.6108.2108.7109.3109.4109.2109.2110.7111.5112.0112.3Transportation49.449.850.651.049.849.551.255.755.555.555.458.364.371.677.079.084.089.692.190.889.791.396.599.7103.8103.8105.0107.2107.8109.3111.1112.7111.1110.6110.6111.0111.4111.2111.5111.0111.0111.2111.5111.6111.2111.1111.4112.0112.0112.2113.5113.5113.3114.3114.5113.8Medicalcare49.449.650.050.250.250.350.652.054.556.257.560.765.769.872.073.476.981.183.986.688.691.895.5100.1104.4108.1111.3114.2117.0119.4122.3127.7120.6121.0121.4121.6121.8122.2122.7122.8122.8123.0123.4123.7124.2124.5125.3125.8126.3127.0127.7128.4129.4130.4131.3131.9Personalcare42.643.245.746.746.546.447.652.257.661.763.668.276.279.178.978.986.387.388.188.590.093.797.1100.4102.4104.1104.6106.5107.9109.2109.9112.2110.0110.1110.4110.7111.0111.0108.7109.0109.2109.2109.6110.0110.4110.8111.0111.6112.0112.2112.5112.7113.0113.3113.4113.7Readingandrecreation50.251.052.554.354.455.457.360.065.072.075.077.582.586.789.989.392.092.493.392.492.193.496.9100.8102.4104.9107.2109.6111.5114.1115.2117.1115.0115.2115.4115.9115.9115.7114.6114.3114.8115.2115.4115.4115.7115.9116.6116.8116.8117.0117.2117.4117.5118.0118.3118.4O<strong>the</strong>rgoodsandservices52.752.654.054.555.457.158.259.963.064.767.369.575.478.981.282.686.190.692.894.394.395.898.599.8101.8103.8104.6105.3107.1108.8111.4114.9109.3109.4109.5110.3110.6111.0111.5112.6112.7113.3113.3113.4113.4113. e113.8114.:114.7114. £115.:115..115.'115. {116. (115.


TABLE B-43.—Consumer price indexes, by special groups, 1935-66For city wage earners and clerical workers[1957-59=100]Year or month1935193619371938193919401941194219431944194519461947194819491950195119521953 ..19541955195619571958195919601961196219631964 _.196519661965: Jan..Feb.Mar.Apr.May.June.July.Aug.Sept.Oct..Nov.Dec.1966: Jan..Feb.Mar.Apr-MayJuneJuly.Aug.Sept.Oct..Nov.Dec.Allitems47.848.350.049.148.448.851.356.860.361.362.768.077.883.883.090.592.593.293.693.394.798.0100.7101.5103.1104.2105.4106.7108.1109.9113.1108.9108.9109.0109.3109.6110.1110.2110.0110.2110.4110.6111.0111.0111.6112.0112.5112.6112.9113.3113.8114.1114.5114.6114.7Allitemsfood52.553.054.955.555.155.356.960.962.665.066.569.475.881.382.183.188.490.592.392.893.194.797.9100.1102.0103.7104.8106.1107.4108.9110.4113.0109.8109.8109.9110.1110.3110.3110.2110.2110.6110.9111.2111.3111.1111.3111.6112.2112.5112.8113.2113.4113.8114.4114.8114.9Allitemsshelter46.146.748.246.846.046.349.155.359.560.562.168.479.485.684.184.791.893.693.993.993.494.797.8100.7101.5103.0104.2105.4106.7108.0109.6112.9108.6108.6108.7109.1109.4110.0110.1109.8110.0110.2110.4110.8110.8111.4111.9112.4112.4112.6113.1113.6113.9114.3114.4114.3CommoditiesAllcommodities45.045.647.445.644.745.148.255.260.160.862.669.483.489.487.187.695.596.796.495.594.695.598.5100.8100.9101.7102.3103.2104.1105.2106.4109.2105.6105.5105.6105.9106.2106.9106.9106.6106.6106.9107.1107.4107.4108.0108.4108.8108.8109.0109.3109.8110.0110.3110.2110.1Commodities less foodFood42.142.544.241.039.940.544.251.957.957.158.466.981.388.284.785.895.497.195.695.494.094.797.8101.9100.3101.4102.6103.6105.1106.4108.8114.2106.6106.6106.9107.3107.9110.1110.9110.1109.7109.7109.7110.6111.4113.1113.9114.0113.5113.9114.3115.8115.6115.6114.8114.8All50.250.853.053.052.152.455.061.263.867.370.074.483.990.389.095.696.496.695.694.995.998.899.9101.2101.7102.0102.8103.5104.4105.1106.5104.9104.7104.8105.0105.2105.1104.7104.7104.9105.3105.6105.7105.3105.4105.6106.0106.3106.4106.7106.6107.0107.6107.8107.7Durable47.147.850.851.750.650.253.660.962.968.773.977.383.889.991.292.299.2100.599.897.395.495.498.5100.0101.5100.9100.8101.8102.1103.0102.6102.7103.6103.3103.2103.0102.9102.6102.3101.8101.7102.1102.4102.4101.9101.8102.0102.3102.5102.6103.0103.0102.7103.5103.5103.1Nondurable48.849.251.250.950.150.652.858.460.964.066.371.181.788.086.386.292.793.294.094.494.496.599.199.8101.0102.6103.2103.8104.8105.7107.2109.7106.1106.1106.2106.8107.2107.3106.9107.1107.7108.0108.3108.4108.0108.3108.6109.0109.3109.5109.7109.6110.5110.9111.3111.4ServicesAllservices52.252.854.455.455.555.756.458.259.360.761.562.765.369.472.675.078.982.486.088.790.592.896.6100.3103.2106.6108.8110.9113.0115.2117.8122.3116.6116.9117.0117.3117.5117.6117.8117.9118.5118.7119.0119.3119.5119.7120.1121.1121.5122.0122.6123.0123.5124.1124.7125.2Rent56.958.360.962.963.063.264.365.765.765.966.166.568.773.276.479.182.385.790.393.594.896.598.3100.1101.6103.1104.4105.7106.8107.8108.9110.4108.4108.5108.7108.8108.8108.8108.9109.0109.1109.2109.3109.5109.7109.8109.9110.1110.2110.2110.3110.6110.7111.0111.2111.3Allserviceslessrent49.349.049.549.949.950.050.652.855.257.959.161.264.368.071.473.477.881.584.987.489.491.996.1100.2103.6107.4110.0112.1114.5117.0120.0125.0118.6118.9119.1119.3119.5119.7120.0120.0120.7121.0121.3121.6121.8122.0122.5123.6124.1124.8125.5125.9126.5127.1127.7128.3Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics.263


TABLE B-44.—Wholesale price indexes, by major commodity groups, 7929-66[1957-59=100]Year or monthAllcommoditiesFarmproductsProcessedfoodsAll commodities o<strong>the</strong>r than farm productsand foods (industrials)TotalTextileproductsandapparelHides,skins,lea<strong>the</strong>r,andlea<strong>the</strong>rproductsFuelsandrelatedproducts,andpower1929193019311932193319341935193619371938193919401941194219431944194519461947194819491950195119521953195419551956195719581959I9601961196219631964...19651966 *1965: Jan..Feb..Mar..Apr_.May..June-July..Aug..Sept..Oct..Nov..Dec...1966: Jan..Feb..Mar.Apr..May.June.July.Aug.Sept.Oct_.Nov.Dec*52.147.339.935.636.141.043.844.247.243.042.243.047.854.056.556.957.966.181.287.983.586.896.794.092.792.993.296.299.0100.4100.6100.7100.3100.6100.3100.5102.5105.8101.0101.2101.3101.7102.1102.8102.9102.9103.0103.1103.5104.1104.6105.4105.4105.5105.6105.7106.4106.8106.8106.2105.9105.963.954.039.629.431.339.948.049.452.741.939.941.350.164.674.875.378.390.6109.1117.1101.3106.4123.8116.8105.9104.497.996.699.2103.697.296.996.097.795.794.398.4105.693.094.595.497.698.4100.3100.099.199.599.4100.3103.0104.5107.4106.8106.4104.5104.2107.8108.1108.7104.4102.5101.854.349.541.633.933.739.648.346.448.642.340.240.446.754.857.256.056.471.791.198.492.6103.3100.997.097.694.394.397.9102.999.2100.0100.7101.2101.1101.0105.1111.5102.2102.1101.8102.3103.3106.1106.6106.7106.7106.9107.6109.4110.3111.8111.5110.6110.5110.6111.7113.8113.8112.4110.7110.651.748.142.439.740.244.244.044.948.146.146.046.850.353.954.755.656.361.775.381.780.082.991.589.490.190.492.496.599.299.5101.3101.3100.8100.8100.7101.2102.5104.7101.9101.9102.0102.1102.3102.5102.5102.7102.7102.8103.2103.2103.5103.8104.0104.3104.7104.9105.2105. 2105.2105.3105.5105.567.860.349.841.248.654.753.353.757.350.152.355.463.772.873.173.975.187.3105.7110.3100.9104.8116.9105.5102.8100.6100,7100.7100.898.9100.4101.599.7100.6100.5101.2101.8102.1101.5101.5101.5101.5101.6101.9101.9101.9102.1102.0101.9102.0101.9102.0102.1102.2102.2102.2102.4102.4102.2102.2102.1101.956.652.044.738.042.044.946.549.554.348.249.652.356.161.161.060.561.370.796.597.592.599.9114.892 894.189.989.594.894.996.0109.1105.2106.2107.4104.2104.6109.2119.7104.9105.1105.7106.3107.4107.7108.8112.2111.3113.3113.6114.6116.0117.8118.7120.6122.8122.9122.7121.2119.9118.7117.5117.561.558.250.052.149.354.354.556.557.556.654.253.256.658.259.961.662.366.779.793.889.390.293.593.395.994.694.597.4102.798.798.7100.7100.299.897.198.9101.398.597.997.997.698.498.798.799.099.299.4100.3100.6100.5100.399.9100.0100.4101.5101.4102.0102.2102.6102. •102.1See footnotes at end <strong>of</strong> table.264


TABLE B-44.—Wholesale price indexes, by major commodity groups, 1929-66—Continued[1957-59=100]Year or month1929 _193019311932 __.1933 _1934193519361937193819391940194119421943 .__1944194519461947 _._19481949 _.19501951 —195219531954195519561957 ._.19581959 _196019611962 ._1963196419651966 *>1965: Jan..Feb_.Mar_.Apr-May.June.July_.Aug..Sept.Oct..Nov..Dec—1966: Jan..Feb..Mar..Apr_.May.June.July_Aug-Sept.Oct._Nov_Dec*All commodities o<strong>the</strong>r than farm products and foods (industrials)—ContinuedRubberandrubberproducts57.650.442.837.139.045.545.849.458.157.159.355.359.669.471.370.468.368.668.370.568.383.2102.192.586.387.699.2100.6100.2100.199.799.996.193.393.892.592.994.892.392.292.292.392.993.193.093.293.393.493.593.593.794.194.395.495.495.495.195.194.794.695.095.0Lumberandwoodproducts26.424.119.616.920.023.522.623.627.925.426.128.934.537.539.742.843.449.777.488.581.994.1102.599.599.497.6102.3103.898.597.4104.1100.495.996.598.6100.6101.1105.6100.8100.8100.7100.5100.4100.3100 5101.8102.0101.6101.6101.9102.8103.7105.6108.4109.6107.7106.6106.2105.9104.8103.0102.5Pulp,paper,andalliedproducts75.378.675.277.191.389.088.788.891.197.299.0100.1101.0101.898.8100.099.299.099.9102.699.099.099.599.8100.0100.0100.0100.5100.8100.9101.2101.3101.8102.3102.7103.0103.2103.2103.1103.1103.0103.0Metalsandmetalproducts44.139.735.732.837.137.037.843.241.641.241.442.242.842.742.743.448.560.268.569.072.780.981.083.684.390.097.899.799.1101.2101.3100.7100.0100.1102.8105.7108.3104.5104.6104.8105.2105.7105.9105.8106.2106.2106.3106.7106.6107.0107.5108.0108.2108.4108.7108.8108.5108.4108.6109.0108.9Machineryandmotiveproducts43.744.245.847.747.447.447.853.661.867.571.272.679.581.282.283.285.892.197.7100.1102.2102.4102.3102.3102.2102.9103.7106.0103.3103.5103.5103.7103.7103.8103.7103.8103.8103.9104.1104.2104.4104.7105.0105.2105.8105.9106.0106.2106.3107.1107.7107.9Furnitureando<strong>the</strong>rhouseholddurables56.455.551.145.045.149.048.649.354.753.453.254.457.862.562.163.863.967.877.882.583.885.692.891.192.993.994.396.999.4100.2100.4100.199.598.898.198.598.099.198.398.298.398.098.098.097.897.797.797.898.098.298.398.498.498.698.998.999.099.199.299.7100.3100.4Nonmetallicmineralproducts53.453.249.746.549.252.652.652.753.952.251.251.252.454.554.755.858.161.869.174.776.778.683.583.586.988.891.395.2101.2101.4101.8101.8101.3101.5101.7102.6101.7101.8101.9101.9101.9102. G101.7101.6101.6101.6101.6101.6102.0102.1102.1102.3102.4102.5102.7102.7103.0103.2103.3103.2Tobaccoproductsandbottledbever-67.467.867.263.356.659.259.159.059.559.459.460.160.861.564.664.966.769.875.678.279.680.585.187.089.893.894.695.198.099.7102.2102.5103.2104.1106.1107.4107.7109.5107.5107.6107.5107.8108.1107.6107.6107.6107.7107.7107.7107.9108.1108.0109.2109.4109.4109.8110.0110.1110.1110.1110.1110.1Miscellaneousproducts108.7111.2103.5104.1113.1116.7105.4110.599.198.196.6101.5101.999.3103.9107.3110.4109.2111.0117.2110.01C9.6109.5110.3iO8.9111.0112.6111.5111.5111.2113.2112.5114.3116.0113.1113.0115.1115.7120.5121.1120.4118.2118.5120.5Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics.265


TABLE B-45.—Wholesale price indexes, by stage <strong>of</strong> processing, 1947—66[1957-59=100]Year ormonth1947.1948194919501951.19521953195419551956195719581959.1960196119621963196419651966 "1965-1966:JanFebMarAprMayJuneJulyAugSeptOctNov.....DecJanFebMarAprMay....JuneJuly....AugSeptOctNovDec P--_-Allcommodities81.287.983.586.896.794.092.792.993.296.299.0100.4100.6100.7100.3100.6100.3100.5102.5105.8101.0101.2101.3101.7102.1102.8102.9102.9103.0103.1103.5104.1104.6105.4105.4105.5105.6105.7106.4106.8106.8106.2105.9105.9Crude materialsTotal100.8110.595.6104.2119.6109.9101.5100.696.797.299.4101.699.096.696.197.195.094.198.9105.394.295.595.896.998.3100.6100.5100.8100.0100.1100.8103.2105.2107.5106.9106.3105.7105.6107.8107.4106.1103.6101.1100.8Foodstuffsandfeedstuffs113.0122.2101.5108.9126.0118.6106.2106.296.294.298.4104.297.496.294.996.894.091.998.3107.291.893.593.995.497.3101.0100.9101.1100.0100.1100.7104.1106.8109.6108.3107.5106.5106.0109.1111.2109.9106.2102.5102.2Nonfoodmaterials,exceptfuel86.596.287.5100.0115.399.995.693.899.1102.8101.497.6101.096.897.997.496.297.899.8101.998.398.799.099.7100.299.899.6100.099.9100.1100.7101.3102.2103.8104.6104.5104.5105.1105.7100.298.998.297.697.4FuelIntermediate materials, supplies, and components lTotalMaterials and components formanufacturingTotalMaterialsforfoodmanufacturingMaterialsfornondurablemanufacturingMaterialsfordurablemanufacturingComponentsformanufacturingMaterialsandcomponentsforconstruction73.687.086.586.187.788.391.487.387.193.398.699.8101.6102.5102.3101.8103.0102.5103.3106.3103.5104.3103.6101.5101.5101.7101.9102.7103.7104.3104.8105.4105.6105.9105.2104.0105.0105.3105.5106.2107.0108.1108.9109.176.582.779.483.093.090.390.891.393.097.199.499.6101.0101.0100.3100.2100.5100.9102.2104.8101.6101.6101.6101.8101.9102.2102.3102.4102.5102.6103.0103.0103.4103.8103.9104.3104.8104.9105.4105.8105.6105.3105.3105.475.581.578.081.892.788.890.290.492.696.999.399.7101.0101.099.899.299.4100.4102.0104.0101.5101.4101.5101.6101.7101.9102.0102.1102.2102.4102.5102.6102.8103.2103.4103.7104.1104.1104.4104.8104.6104.3104.4104.5102.6105.891.094.7105.5101.4101.6100.797.597.999.7102.098.399.5102.6100.5105.5104.0106.6111.3106.3106.3105.6105.8104.9105.9106.2106.5106.9107.5108.1108.8109.7111.1110.8110.1109.8110.0111.9114.8113.6111.6111.2110.994.099.590.795.2110.399.398.596.997.398.8100.199.1100.8100.898.698.097.197.898.799.598.598.598.598.698.798.798.798.798.798.998.898.998.999.099.299.499.7100.0100.2100.199.899.599.299.258.866.468.272.180.180.383.985.790.095.798.899.5101.8101.9100.5100.4100.5102.5104.6106.6103.7103.9104.0104.2104.6104.8104.8105.0105.1105.1105.3105.2105.5105.8106.1106.6106.8106.7106.6106.9106.8106.8107.0107.163.068.069.371.981.681.883.383.787.495.499.199.9101.1100.699.698.898.899.7101.3104.8100.4100.5100.5100.7101.2101.4101.4101.6101.6101.9102.2102.3102.5102.9103.3104.1104.8105.0105.1105.4105.5105.9106.6107.077.077.281.288.888.289.790.193.798.599.199.1101.8101.199.799.399.6100.6101.4104.0100.9100.9100.9101.0101.2101.2101.3101.7101.7101.7101.8101.9102.3102.7103.4104.3104.8104.5104.5104.6104 6104.5104.3104.2See footnotes at end <strong>of</strong> table.266


TABLE B^45.— Wholesale price indexes, by stage <strong>of</strong> processing, 1947-66—Continued[1957-59=100]Finished goodsSpecial groups <strong>of</strong> industrialproductsYear or monthTotalTotalConsumer finishedgoodsFoodsO<strong>the</strong>rnondurablegoodsDurablegoodsProducerfinishedgoodsCrudematerials2Intermediatematerials,supplies,and components3Consumerfinishedgoods excludingfoods1947194819491950195119521953195480.186.484.085.593.693.092.192.386.192.698.297.095.495.390.799.091.092.8104.2103.397.997.186.592.088.289.696.594.195.095.375.981.183.284.189.790.491.191.861.867.470.772.479.580.882.183.179.292.584.093.6102.993.192.488.073.479.877.881.491.288.389.483.188.486.587.894.292.993.794.11955195619571958195992.595.198.6100.8100.694.796.198.9101.0100.194.794.597.8103.598.795.897.799.999.3100.892.895.998.7100.1101.385.692.097.7100.2102.196.6102.3100.996.9102.392.597.099.699.4101.094.897.199.599.6100.9196019611962..19631964101.4101.4101.7101.4101.8101.1100.9101.2100.7100.9100.8100.4101.3100.1100.6101.5101.5101.6101.9101.6100.9100.5100.099.5102.3102.5102.9103.1104.198.397.295.694.397.1101.4100.199.999.6100.2101.3101.2101.0101.0100.919651966 »103.6106.9102.8106.4104.5111.2102.8104.899.6100.2105.4108.0100.9104.5101.5103.6101.7103.21965: Jan...Feb..Mar..Apr..May-June.102.3102.3102.4102.8103.2103.9101.2101.2101.4101.9102.3103.2100.8100.9101.3102.6103.5105.6102.3102.2102.2102.2102.5102.699.799.799.799.699.7104.9105.0105.1105.3105.3105.499.099.499.7100.1101.0100.5100.8100.8100.9101.1101.4101.5101.4101.3101.3101.3101.5101.6July..Aug..Sept..Oct...Nov..Dec.104.0103.8104.1104.3104.7105.3103.4103.1103.5103.7104.2104.9106.0105.3106.1106.3107.2108.9102.7102.8103.0103.3103.6103.799.699.599.599.599.6105.4105.5105.5105.6105.9106.0100.4101.7101.3102.0102.7102.6101.5101.7101.8101.9102.1102.2101.6101.6101.8102.0102.2102.31966: Jan...Feb_.Mar..Apr..May-June.105.6106.3106.4106.3106.2106.4105.2106.0106.1105.9105.6105.7109.5111.5111.5110.7109.6109.5103.9104.0104.1104.3104.5104.999.799.799.799.8100.2100.1106.2106.6106.8107.0107.6107.9104.0105.7106.6106.1105.9106.5102.4102.6102.9103.4103.8103.9102.4102.4102.5102.8103.0103.2July..Aug..Sept..Oct...Nov..Dec*107.0107.5108.1107.8107.8107.6106.4107.1107.8107.2107.0106,6111.2112.8114.5112.2111.3110.5105.0105.2105.4105.5105.7105.5100.2100.1100.0100.9101.2101.3108.1108.3108.4109.1109.8110.0106.4103.3102.8102.8102. 7101.7104.0104.2104.1104.1104.1104.1103.3103.4103.5103.9104.1104.01 Includes, in addition to subgroups shown, processed fuels and lubricants, containers, and supplies.2 Excludes crude foodstuffs and feedstuffs, plant and animal fibers, oilseeds, and leaf tobacco.3 Excludes intermediate materials for food manufacturing and manufactured animal feeds.NOTE.—For a listing <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> commodities included in each sector, see Table 2B, Wholesale Prices and PriceIndexes, 1963 (BLS Bulletin 1513).Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor, Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics.267


MONEY SUPPLY, CREDIT, AND FINANCETABLE B-46.—Money supply, 1947-66[Averages <strong>of</strong> daily figures,billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year and monthTotalMoney supplyTotalmoneysupplyandtimedepositsadjustedCurrencycomponent1Demanddepositcomponent2Timedepositsadjusted3TotalmoneysupplyandtimedeposadS -justedMoney supplyU.S.Time GovernmentCurrencmandad-de-De-positsTotal com-deposit just-ed 3 demanponent1 component2 its 4Seasonally adjustedUnadjusted1947: Dec.1948: Dec.1949: Dec.148.5147.5147.6113.1111.5111.226.425.825.186.785.886.035.436.036.4151. 0150.0150.0115.9114.3113.926.826.225.589.188.188.435.135.736.11.01.82.81950: Dec.1951: Dec.1952: Dec.1953: Dec.1954: Dec.152.9160.9168.5173.3180.6116.2122.7127.4128.8132.325.026.127.327.727.491.296.5100.1101.1104.936.738.241.144.548.3155.6163.8171.7176.3183.6119.2125.8130.8132.1135.625.426.627.828.227.993.899.2103.0103.9107.736.438.040.944.248.02.42.74.93.85.01955: Dec.1956: Dec.1957: Dec.1958: Dec.1959: Dec.185.2188.8193.3206.5209.3135.2136.9135.9141.1141.927.828.228.328.628.9107.4108.7107.6112.6113.150.051.957.465.467.4188.2191.7196.0209.3212.2138.6140.3139.3144.7145.628.428.828.929.229.5110.2111.5110.4115.5116.149.651.456.764.666.63.43.43.53.94.91960: Dec.1961: Dec.1962: Dec.1963: Dec.1964: Dec.214.0228.2245.3265.3286.3141.1145.5147.5153.1159.728.929.630.632.534.2112.1116.0116.9120.6125.472.982.797.8112.2126.6216.8231.2248.3268.3289.2144.7149.4151.6157.3164.029.630.231.233.135.0115.2119.2120.3124.1129.172.181.896.7111.0125.24.74.95.65.15.51965: Dec.1966: Dec ».314.1328.2167.2170.236.338.2130.9132.0146.9158.0317.2331.4172.0175.137.139.0134.9136.1145.2156.34.63.51965: Jan...Feb..Mar..Apr..May-June.288.4290.5292.3294.3295.3297.9159.7159.8160.3161.0160.7161.734.534.634.734.834.935.0125.3125.2125.6126.2125.8126.7128.7130.7132.0133.3134.6136.2292.7290.3291.6295.5292.9296.1164.4159.5158.9161.5157.5159.534.434.234.434.534.634.9130.1125.2124.6127.1122.9124.5128.3130.8132.7134.0135.4136.64.25.76.65.59.59.1July..Aug..Sept..Oct...Nov..Dec.300.3303.0305.7308.9311.1314.1162.4163.0164.1195.2165.6167.235.335.535.736.036.136.3127.2127.5128.5129.3129.5130.9137.9140.0141.6143.7145.5146.9299.1300.5304.5309.2311.6317.2160.8160.3163.1165.7167.3172.035.435.535.736.036.537.1125.4124.8127.5129.7130.8134.9138.3140.2141.4143.5144.3145.29.07.35.55.04.14.61966: Jan...Feb..Mar._M P a F y."June-July..Aug..Sept..Oct...Nov..Dec 9,315.8316.7318.8322.3323.25 324. 8324.9326.2327.6326.4326.1328.2168.0168.2169.3170.9170.2171.1169.6169.6170.5169.6169.2170.236.636.836.937.237.337.437.737.837.937.938.038.2131.4131.4132.3133.7132.9133.7132.0131.8132.6131.7131.1132.0147.8148.5149.5151.4153.0«153.7155.3156.6157.1156.8156.9158.0320.3316.5318.0323.8320.85 322.9323.7323.9326.4326.7326.6331.4173.0167.8167.8171.6166.9168.8167.9166.9169.5170.1171.0175.136.536.436.636.837.037.337.837.937.938.038.539.0136.5131.4131.3134.8129.9131.5130.1129.1131.5132.1132.5136.1147.3148.7150.2152.2153.9«154.1155.8157.0156.9156.6155.6156.33.85.24.63.17.26.38.25.24.54.83.73.51 Currency outside <strong>the</strong> Treasury, <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System, and <strong>the</strong> vaults <strong>of</strong> all commercial banks.2 Demand deposits at all commercial banks, o<strong>the</strong>r than those due to domestic commercial banks and <strong>the</strong>U.S. Government, less cash items in process <strong>of</strong> collection and Federal Reserve float, and foreign demandbalances at Federal Reserve banks.3 Time deposits adjusted are time deposits at all commercial banks o<strong>the</strong>r than those due to domesticcommercial banks and <strong>the</strong> U.S. Government.4 Deposits at all commercial banks.s Effective June 1966, balances accumulated for payment <strong>of</strong> personal loans were reclassified for reservepurposes and are excluded from time deposits reported by member banks. The estimated amount <strong>of</strong> suchdeposits at all commercial banks ($1.1 billion) is excluded from time deposits adjusted <strong>the</strong>reafter.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning January 1959 and August 1959, respectively.Source: Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System.268


TABLE B-47.—Selected liquid assets held by <strong>the</strong> public, 1946-66 l[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars, seasonally adjusted]End <strong>of</strong> year or monthTotalDemanddepositsandcurrency 2Time depositsCommercialbanks 3MutualsavingsbanksPostalsavingssystemSavingsandloansharesU.S.Governmentsavingsbonds *U.S.Governmentsecuritiesmaturingwithin1 year *194619471948_ _1949239.1246.2254.1262.1108.5112.4110.5110.433.935.335.936.316.917.818.419.33.33.43.33.28.59.711.012.548.650.953.455.019.416.621.625.51950...195119521953 _1954271.4281.0296.0311.5320.3115.5120.9125.5127.3130.236.638.241.244.648.220.120.922.624.426.32.92.72.52.42.114.016.119.222.827.255.855.455.755.655.626.426.829.334.419551956195719581959332.5343.2356.0373.1393.9133.3134.6133.5138.8139.749.752.057.565.467.428.130.031.633.934.91.91.61.31.1.932.037.041.747.754.355.954.851.650.547.931.633.238.835.648.8196019611962 __19631964399.2424.6459.0495.4530.5138.4142.6144.8149.6156.773.182.598.1112.9127.136.238.341.444.549.0.8.6.5.5.461.870.579.890.9101.447.047.447.649.049.941.942.646.848.146.119651966"572.9599.6164.0168.5147.1158.452.654.8.3.1109.7113.250.550.948.653.61965: Jan..Feb—Mar..May.June.534.9536.5542.9543.4543.0550.2156.1154.8158.6156.3155.4159.7130.6131.9133.0134.1134.9136.349.449.649.850.150.450.8.4.4.4.4.4.3101.7102.6103.7103.9104.5105.150.049.949.949.949.950.046.847.347.648.647.6'48.0July—Aug.Sept—Oct—Nov.Dec —1966: Jan..Feb..Mar,.Apr..May..June_.July..Aug..Sept..Oct p.Nov pDec p550.9555.7560.7565.1568.3572.9578.5577.5585.5587.0585.78 589.1588.4592.8594.2596.0600.2599.6157.7157.8160.6161.1160.4164.0164.8162.7167.0166.4163.7166.5164.3167.0166.1166.0167.8168.5138.3139.8141.6144.0146.5147.1149.2149.4151.1152.5153.65153.9156.1156.6156.7156.6158.2158.451.151.351.652.052.352.652.853.053.153.153.353.453.753.954.254.654.854.8.4.3.3.3.3.3.3.3.3.3.3.2.2.2.2.2.1.1105.5106.5107.8108.4109.3109.7109.8110.6111.4111.0111.2111.4110.7111.3112.2112.1112.8113.250.150.150.150.150.150.550.550.350.350.450.450.450.650.650.550.650.650.947.949.848.749.149.448.651.251.052.153.353.353.452.753.354.456.055.853.61 Excludes holdings <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> U.S. Government, Government agencies and trust funds, domestic commercialbanks, and Federal Reserve banks. Adjusted wherever possible to avoid double counting.2 Agrees in concept with <strong>the</strong> money supply, Table B-46, except for deduction <strong>of</strong> demand deposits heldby mutual savings banks and savings and loan associations. Data are for last Wednesday <strong>of</strong> month.3 Time deposits at all commercial banks o<strong>the</strong>r than those due to domestic commercial banks and <strong>the</strong>U.S. Government (same concept as in Table B-46). Data are for last Wednesday <strong>of</strong> month, except thatJune 30 and December 31 call data are used where available.4 Excludes holdings <strong>of</strong> Government agencies and trust funds, domestic commercial and mutual savingsbanks, Federal Reserve banks, and beginning February 1960, savings and loan associations.s Effective June 1966, balances accumulated for <strong>the</strong> payment <strong>of</strong> personal loans (about $1.1 billion) areexcluded from time deposits at all commercial banks and from total liquid assets.NOTE.—Series for all commercial banks include data for Alaska and Hawaii beginning January 1959 andAugust 1959, respectively, except that one national bank in Alaska and one national bank in Hawaii wereincluded in April 1954 and April 1959, respectively.Source: Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System.240-782 O—67- -18269


TABLE B-48.—Financial saving by individuals, 1939-66 3[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year or quarterTotalCurrencyandbankdepositsSavingssharesTotalSecuritiesU.S.savingsbondsando<strong>the</strong>rO<strong>the</strong>rgovernment*CorporatePrivateanceandpensionreservesNoninsuredpensionfundsGovernmentnsuranceandpensionreserves4Less:Increase indebtMortdebt*ConsumeritiesSecu-debt« loans?1939194019411942194319441945194619471948194919501951195219531954195519561957 _ - - .195819591960196119621963 -196419651966 P3.02.98.827.135.938.435.013.25.0.51.6-.38.110.49.08.55.212.215.019.714.06.318.922.124.631.833.127.83.02.94.810.916.217.519.010.62.0-1.8-1.43.55.97.04.75.43.44.84.810.24.12.49.517.718.419.425.410.00.1.3.4.3.6.91.11.21.31.31.61.72.33.34.04.75.25.35.26.47.28.29.29.911.711.39.34.3-0.8-.42.610.314.115.79.9-1.42.23.02.3.9.73.43.4.26.25.25.31.110.2-1.01.1— .41.67.04.914.90.7.92.88.011.111.86.91.02.01.61.5.3 -.1— .5 -.5.1 1.2.2 2.0.6 -1.13.73.2-I!Q 4.4-1.1-L8 11.0.8.41.2.9.6.5-0.9-.8.42.33.34.64.2-2.6-.2.5.1-.9-.6.72.55.74.212.6-0.6-.4-.5*-.3-.7-1.2.2.4.9.7.71.62.11.2.62.32.02.72.61.0.11.0-1.5-2.1.4.11.71.51.61.92.22.62.93.23.13.53.33.53.73.84.44.54.75.05.04.64.84.94.85.25.76.26.77.46.50.1.1.1.1.2.6.9.3.3.4.6.91.51.72.02.22.32.73.13.23.64.04.14.24.54.95.65.60.3.3.3.71.32.33.12.51.72.01.8-.61.71.91.71.71.82.32.62.93.03.23.23.74.04.65.04.90.59.8 1-.4-.1.23.13.94.73.96.57.06.17.28 312.010.68.18.212.510.910.912.514.615.615.413.10.81 0.7— 3 0-1.0.1. .52.32.82.42.63.71.04.43.71.06.23.32.5.26.14.21.55.06.36.59.06.9-0.2— 2-.1 3.61.41.5-2.3— 8Ạ3.2-.3.6.4.9.6-.8-.1.4.2.31.01.1.9.1*-1.61964: IIIIIIIV1965: I IIIIIIV1966* I IIIIIrv* p..6.86.08 310.76.16.010.610.35.55.19 57.61.83.85 78.11.95.08.010.4— 1.42.44 24.72.53.32 13.52.12.51.43.31.41.0— 62.51.81.92 01 21.31.91.0.64.93.74 51.71.71.51 9.91.21.1.94.22.23 82.4-.1 .31__.6i.61.4 .6—.91.51.51 72.01.71.51.92.21.81.51.51.81.11.31.41.41.31.31.71.21.31.31.8.91.21 31.31.11.31.31.31.11.21 31.34.13.83 64.13.73.34.04.44.53.02 13.5-.72.61 63 0-.33.52.43.4— .42.61 63.2-.6.63— .3-.1.7-2.01.5— .4.3— 1.0-.51 Individuals' saving, in addition to personal holdings, covers saving <strong>of</strong> unincorporated business, trustfunds, and nonpr<strong>of</strong>it institutions in <strong>the</strong> forms specified.2 Includes shares in savings and loan associations and shares and deposits in credit unions.3 "O<strong>the</strong>r government" includes U.S. Government issues (except savings bonds), State and local governmentsecurities, and nonguaranteed Federal agency issues.4 Includes civil service, railroad retirement, and State and local retirement systems.8 Mortgage debt to institutions on one- to four-family nonfarm dwellings.6 Consumer debt owed to corporations, largely attributable to purchase <strong>of</strong> automobiles and o<strong>the</strong>r durableconsumer goods, although including some debt arising from purchases <strong>of</strong> consumption goods. Policyloans on Government and private life insurance have been deducted from those items <strong>of</strong> saving.7 Change in bank loans to brokers, dealers, and o<strong>the</strong>rs for <strong>the</strong> purpose <strong>of</strong> purchasing or carrying securities.NOTE.—In addition to <strong>the</strong> concept <strong>of</strong> saving shown above, <strong>the</strong>re are o<strong>the</strong>r concepts <strong>of</strong> individuals' saving,with varying degrees <strong>of</strong> coverage, currently in use. The personal saving estimates <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong>Commerce are derived as <strong>the</strong> difference between personal income (after taxes) and personal outlays. Fora reconciliation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two series, see Securities and Exchange Commission Statistical Bulletin, July 1966,and Survey <strong>of</strong> Current Business, July 1966.The flow-<strong>of</strong>-funds system <strong>of</strong> accounts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System includesestimates <strong>of</strong> gross saving and net financial investment <strong>of</strong> households.Data for Alaska and Hawaii included for all periods.Source: Securities and Exchange Commission.270


End <strong>of</strong> year or month l1929< .1930 *1931* _1932 41933 4193441935. _.19361937 ._ _ -1938193919401941 ___19421943194419451946 _19471948194819491950 -195119521953 - _1954 -_._19551956195719581959 -_196019611962*1963«196419651966 51§65- JanFebMarAprMayJune. - -._-- .. .JulyAugSeptOctNovDec_ _1966: JanFeb ....MarAprMayJune. ... . .JulyAugSept.-Oct pNov p . _Dec 6 ....TABLE B-49.—Bank loans and investments, 1929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Totalloansandinvestments2 49.448.944.936.130.432.736.139.638.438.740.743.950.767.485.1105.5124.0114.0116.3114.2113.0118.7124.7130.2139.1143.1153.1157.6161.6166.4181.2185.9194.5209.6227.9246.2267.2294.4310.7269.6272.1275.8277.0279.4281.7283.2286.1286.2289.9291.5294.4297.4297.5300.3302.9304.98 307.7309.2310.8308.7308.1308.4310.7All commercial banksInvestmentsLoans 2 U.S. GovernmentsecuritiesO<strong>the</strong>rsecurities35.734.529.221.816.315.715.216.417.216.417.218.821.719.219.121.626.131.138.142.4Seasonally adjusted41.542.051.156.562.866.269.180.688.191.595.6107.5113.8120.5134.1149.7167.4192.0208.2170.2172.8175.4177.1179.4181.4182.9185.2186.2188.6189.8192.0194.5196.2198.6200.8202.36 204.0206.4206.6206.1207.3207.3208.24.95.06.06.27.510.313.815.314.215.116.317.821.841.459.877.690.674.869.262.662.366.461.160.462.262.267.660.357.256.965.157.959.865.264.561.561.157.754.360.059.459.958.758.758.257.957.756.557.457.557.758.055.956.055.955.155.154.456.154.352.452.954.38.79.49.78.16.56.77.17.97.07.27.17.47.26.86.16.37.38.19.09.29.210.312.413.414.214.716.416.816.317.920.520.520.823.929.235.038.744.848.339.540.040.541.241.342.142.443.143.443.944.244.844.945.445.746.247.46 48.648.548.148.348.448.348.3Weekly reportingmemberbanksBusinessloans*5.14.24.75.37.16.36.46.57.311.314.715.615.613.917.921.623.423.422.426.730.831.831.730.732.232.935.238.842.150.660.641.843.044.644.645.246.846.346.948.148.249.050.650.351.152.652.553.555.8New series 758.758.359.459.559.960.61 Data are for last Wednesday <strong>of</strong> month (except June 30 and December 31 call dates used for all commercialbanks).2 Adjusted to exclude interbank loans beginning 1948.3 Commercial and industrial loans and prior to 1956, agricultural loans. Beginning July 1959, loans t<strong>of</strong>inancial institutions excluded. Prior to 1943, published data adjusted to include open market paper.4 June data used because complete end-<strong>of</strong>-year data not available.* Commercial bank data are estimates for December 31.6 Effective June 1966, balances accumulated for payment <strong>of</strong> personal loans (about $1.1 billion) are excludedfrom loans at all commercial banks, and certain certificates <strong>of</strong> CCC and Export-Import Bank totalingabout $1 billion are included in o<strong>the</strong>r securities ra<strong>the</strong>r than in loans.7 See Federal Reserve Bulletin, August 1966.NOTE.—National bank data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning April 1954 and April 1959, respectively.All o<strong>the</strong>r bank data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning January 1959 and August 1959,respectively.Source: Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System.271


TABLE B-50.—Bond yields and interest rates, 1929-66(Percent per annum]Year or monthU.S. Government securities3-monthTreasurybills i9-12monthissues 23-5yearissues »Taxablebonds 4Corporatebonds(Moody's)AaaBaaHighgrademunicipalbonds(Standard&Poor's)Averagerate onshorttermbankloansto businessselectedcitiesPrimecommercialpaper,monthsFederalReserveBankdiscountrate192919301931193219331934( 5 )(5)1.402879.5152562.662.124.734.554.585.014.494.005.905.907.629.307.766.324.274.074.014.654.714.03( 6 )(6)V(8)5.853.592.642.731.731.025.163.042.112.822.561.541935 __193619371938____1939.137.143.447.053.0231.291.111.40.83.593.603.243.263.193.015.754.775.035.804.963.403.073.102.912.76(6)(6)2.1.75.75.94.81.591.501.501.331.001.0019401941 _ __194219431944194519461947 _19481949.014.103.326.373.375.375.375.5941.0401.1020.75.79.81.82.881 141.14.50.731.461.341.331.181.161.321.621.432.462.472.482.372.192.252.442.312.842.772.832.732.722.622.532.612.822.664.754.334.283.913.613.293.053.243.473.422.502.102.362.061.861.671.642.012.402.212.12.02.22.62.4" 2.22.12.68.56.53.66.69.73.75.811.031.441.491.001.007 1.0071.007 1.007 1.007 1.001.001.341.50195019511952195319541.2181.5521.7661.931.9531.261.731.812.07921.501.932.132.561.822.322.572.682.942.552.622.862.963.202.903.243.413.523.743.511.982.002.192.722.372.693.113.493.693.611.452.162.332.521.581.591.751.751.991.6019551956195719581959196019611962 _ _ _ _ _1963196419651966 - __- — _1.7532.6583 2671 8393.4052.9282.3782.7783.1573.5493.9544.8811 892.833 532 094.113 552.913.023 283.764 095.172.503.123.622.904.333.993.603.573.724.064.225.162.843.083.473.434.084.023.903.954.004.154.214.653.063.363.893.794.384.414.354.334.264.404.495.133.533.884.714.735.055.195.085.024.864.834.875.672.532.933.603.563.953.733.463.183.233.223.273.823.704.204 624.348 5.005.164.975.005.014.995.066.002.183.313.812.463.973.852.973.263.553.974.385.551.892.773.122.163.363.533.003.003.233.554.044.501964: JanFeb-MarAprMay -__June__JulyAugSeptOct .Nov.___Dec3.5293.5323.5533.4843.4823.4783.4793.5063.5273.5753.6243.8563.663.633.673.633.673.833.683.733.823.833.883.964.064.024.154.184.074.033.993.994.034.044.044.074.154.144.184.204.164.134.134.144.164.164.124.144.374.364.384.404.414.414.404.414.424.424.434.444.834.834.834.854.854.854.834.824.824.814.814.813.233.173.323.293.213.203.183.203.253.263.183.154.994.994.985.003.973.884.003.913.894.003.963.883.894.004.024.173.503.503.503.503.503.503.503.503.503.503.624.00See footnotes at end <strong>of</strong> table.272


TABLE B-50.—Bond yields and interest rates, 7929-66—Continued[Percent per annum]Year or monthU.S. Government securities3-monthTreasurybills 19-12month3-5yearTaxableissues 3 bonds *Corporatebonds(Moody's)AaaBaaHighgrademunicipalbonds(Standard&Poor's)Averagerate onshorttermbankloansto businessselectedcitiesPrimecommercialpaper,4-6monthsFederalReserveBankdiscountrate1065: Jan..Feb.Mar.Apr.May.June.3.8283.9293.9423.9323.8953.8103.873.974.034.003.993.984.064.084.124.124.114.094.144.164.154.154.144.144.434.414.424.434.444.464.804.784.784.804.814.853.063.103.183.173.193.264.974.994.254.274.384.384.384.384.004.004.004.004.004.00July.Aug.Sept.Oct..Nov.Dec.1966: Jan..Feb.Mar.Apr.May.June.July.Aug.Sept.Oct-Nov.Dec.3.8313.8363.9124.0324.0824.3624.5964.6704.6264.6114.6424.5394.8554.9325.3565.3875.3445.0073.964.004.114.184.294.664.834.924.964.874.904.945.175.525.805.575.455.104.104.194.244.334.464.774.895.024.944.864.945.015.225.585.625.385.435.074.154.194.254.284.344.434.434.614.634.554.574.634.754.804.794.704.744.654.484.494.524.564.604.684.744.784.924.964.985.075.165.315.495.415.355.394.884.884.914.934.955.025.065.125.325.415.485.585.685.836.096.106.136.183.263.253.363.423.473.563.523.633.723.593.683.773.944.174.113.973.933.835.005.275.555.826.306.314.384.384.384.384.384.654.824.885.215.385.395.515.635.855.896.006.006.004.004.004.004.004.004.424.504.504.504.504.504.504.504.504.504.504.504.50i Rate on new issues within period. Issues were tax exempt prior to March 1, 1941, and fully taxable<strong>the</strong>reafter. For <strong>the</strong> period 1934-37, series includes issues with maturities <strong>of</strong> more than 3 months.* Certificates <strong>of</strong> indebtedness and selected note and bond issues (fully taxable).3 Selected note and bond issues. Issues were partially tax exempt prior to 1941, and fully taxable <strong>the</strong>reafter.* First issued in 1941. Series includes bonds which are nei<strong>the</strong>r due nor callable before a given number <strong>of</strong>years as follows: April 1953 to date, 10 years; April 1952-March 1953, 12 years; October 1941-March 1952,15 years.5 Treasury bills were first issued in December 1929 and were issued irregularly in 1930.«Not available on same basis as for 1939 and subsequent years.7 From October 30,1942, to April 24,1946, a preferential rate <strong>of</strong> 0.50 percent was in effect for advances securedby Government securities maturing in 1 year or less.* Beginning 1959, series revised to exclude loans to nonbank financial institutions.NOTE.—Yields and rates computed for New York City except for short-term bank loans.Sources: Treasury Department, Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System, Moody's InvestorsService, and Standard & Poor's Corporation.273


TABLE B-51.—Federal Reserve Bank credit and member bank reserves, 1929-66[Averages <strong>of</strong> daily figures, millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year and monthReserve Bank credit outstandingTotalU.S.GovernmentsecuritiesAllo<strong>the</strong>r,mainlyfloatMember bank reservesTotalMemberbankborrowingsRequiredExcessMemberbank freereserves(excessreservesless borrowings)1929: Dec.1,6434468013962,3952,347481930: Dec__1931: Dec.1932: Dec.1933: Dec.1934: Dec _1935: Dec.1936: Dec.1937: Dec..1938: Dec.1939: Dec.1,2731,9502,1922,6692,4722,4942,4982,6282,6182,6126447771,8542,4322,4302,4302,4342,5652,5642,51033776328195106716733542924105714232585747472,4152,0692,4352,5884,0375,7166,6656,8798,74511,4732,3422,0101,909i 1,8222,2902,7334,6195,8085,5206,462736052617661,7482,0461,0713,2265,0111940: Dec.1941: Dec.1942: Dec.1943: Dec.1944: Dec.1945: Dec.1946: Dec.1947: Dec.1948: Dec.1949: Dec.2,3052,4046,03511,91419,61224, 74424,74622,85823,97819,0122,1882,2195,54911,16623, 70823, 76721,90523,00218,2879026533415722413411811418048365965470282172984260714,04912,81213,15212, 74914,16816,02716,51717,26119,99016,2917,4039,42210,77611,70112,88414,53615,61716,27519,19315,4886,6463,3902,3761,0481,2841,4919009867971950: Dec.1951: Dec.1952: Dec.1953: Dec.1954: Dec.1955: Dec.1956: Dec.1957: Dec.1958: Dec.1959: Dec.21,60625,44627,29927,10726,31726,85327,15626,18628,41229,43520,34523,40924,40025,63924,91724, 60224,76523,98226,31227,0361426571,5934412467105579061,1191,3801,3061,0271,1541,4121,7031,4941,5431,49317,39120,31021,18019,92019,27919,24019,53519,42018,8992 18,93216,36419,48420,45719,22718,57618,64618,88318,84318,38318,4501,0278267236937035946525775164821960: Dec.1961: Dec.1962: Dec.1963: Dec.1964: Dec.1965: Dec...1966: Dec *.29,06031, 21733, 21836, 61039,87343,85346,86427,24829,09830, 54633,72937,12640,88543, 740871493043272434545571,7251,9702,3682,5542,5042,5142,56719,28320,11820,04020,74621,60922, 71923,82518,52719,55019,46820,21021,19822,26723, 4307565685725364114521965: Jan...Feb...Mar...Apr...May..June.39,24539,24439,53539,88240,34041,15337,05237, 31537,63738, 11138,8402994054164715055282,2621,7871,8041,7741,7241,78521,62021,23121,24621, 51121,47221, 70921,21520,79020,90521,14521,14721,363405441341366325346July..Aug_.Sept..Oct..Nov..Dec...41,65141,50441,61042,04842,64943,85339,24939,31839,10839,60140,12840,8855245645284904524541,8781,6221,9741,9572,0692,51421,86321,61721,74021,95821,95822,71921,51321,18721,35621,61421,58922,2673504303843443694521966: Jan...Feb..Mar..Apr...May-June..43,44943,11642,94343,33943,89144,49840,62640,63540,62941,12941,6724024785516267226742,4212,0031,9942,0842,0402,15222, 75022,23322,16022,52822,48722,53422,39221,86221,85522,17022,11722,212358371305358370322July..Aug..Sept..Oct.-Nov..Dec*.45,73745,34845,63145,60446,08746,86442,22142,28042,73542,83743,34743,7407667287667336115572,7502,3402,1302,0342,1292,56723,09022,65523,24023,33323,25123,82522,68222,31722, 84223,03122,86223,4304083383983023893961 Data from March 1933 through April 1934 are for licensed banks only.2 Beginning December 1959, total reserves held include vault cash allowed.NOTE.—Data for member banks in Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1954 and 1959, respectively.Source: Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System.274


TABLE B-52.—Short- and intermediate-term consumer credit outstanding, 7929-66[Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Instalment creditNoninstalment creditEnd <strong>of</strong> year or monthTotalTotalAutomobilepaperO<strong>the</strong>rconsumergoodspaperRepairandmodernizationloans iPersonalloansTotalChargeaccountsO<strong>the</strong>r 219291930 .193119321933 .193419351936 . . _1937193819391940...19411942 .194319441945..194619471948. _ _1949195019511952.1953195419551956195719581959___196019611962...1963 -__196419651966 37,1166,3515,3154,0263,8854,2185,1906,3756,9486,3707,2228,3389,1725,9834,9015,1115,6658,38411,59814,44717,36421, 47122,71227,52031,39332,46438,83042.33444,97045,12951,54256,02857,67863,16470, 46178,44287.88495,0003,5243,0222,4631,6721,7231,9992,8173,7474,1183,6864,5035,5146,0853,1662,1362,1762,4624,1726,6958,99611, 59014,70315,29419, 40323,00523, 56828,90631,72033,86733,64239,24542,83243,52748,03454,15860, 54868, 56574,7001,3849866843564936149921,3721,4941,0991,4972,0712,4587423553974559811,9243,0184,5556,0745,9727,7339,8359,80913,46014,42015,34014,15216,42017,68817,22319,54022,43325,19528,84331,0001,5441,4321,214834799889,000,290,5051,442,6201,8271,929,1958197918161,2902,1432,9013,7064,7994,8806,1746,7796,7517,6418,6068,8449,02810,63011,52511,85712,60513,85615, 59317,69319, 7002725221815372533642192182983713762551301191824057188538981,0161,0851,3851,6101,6161,6931,9052,1012,3462,8093,1393,1913,2463,4053,5323,6753,8005695795434644164595727219009271,0881,2451,3229748328691,0091,4961,9102,2242,4312,8143,3574,1114,7815,3926,1126,7897,5828,1169,38610,48011,25612,64314,46416,22818,35420,2003,5923,3292,8522,3542,1622,2192,3732,6282,8302,6842,7192,8243,0872,8172,7652,9353,2034,2124,9035,4515,7746,7687,4188,1178,3888,8969,92410,61411,10311,48712,29713,19614,15115,13016,30317.89419.31920,3001,9961,8331,6351,3741,2861,3061,3541,4281,5041,4031,4141,4711,6451,4441,4401,5171,6122,0762,3812,7222,8543,3673,7004,1304,2744,4854,7954,9955,1465,0605,1045,3295,3245,6845,8716,3006,7467,2001,5961,4961,2179808769131,0191,2001,3261,2811,3051,3531,4421,3731,3251,4181,5912,1362,5222,7292,9203,4013,7183,9874,1144.4115,1295,6195,9576,4277,1937,8678,8279,44610,43211,59412, 57313,1001965: Jan77,783Feb77,406Mar77,796Apr79,237May. _ -.-- 80,469June81,71760,44260,43660,86161,88662,80763,85025,23125,38325,69126,23526,71727,28015, 45515,21815,18015,29215,45815,6483,5053, 4793,4753,4883,5343,57616,25116,35616.51516,87117.09817,34617,34116,97016,93517,35117,66217,8675,7245,1544,9775,2105.4535,52811,61711,81611,95812,14112,20912,339JulyAugSept. __OctNov ... _Dec- -- _..82,53983,31983,80184,46585,29187,88464,70465,50865,97966, 51167,16868,56527,77928, 11128,17528,39328,61228,84315,81815,99616,22916,49216,79717,6933,6043,6483,6643,6763,6893,67517,50317,75317,91117,95018,07018,35417,83517.81117,82217,95418,12319,3195,5345,4985,4965,6455,7406,74612,30112,31312,32612,30912,38312,5731966: JanFebMarApr _May.. -_ -June87,02786,56587,05988,18489,09290,07068,31468,27968,82769,54370,20971,19428,78928,89429,24829,59729,90830,40217,56617,38617,45017,59717,73217,9593,6343,6033,5973,6023,6423,67718,32518,39618,53218.74718.92719,15618,71318,28618,23218,64118,88318,8766,1075,5055,3935,6705,8605,90812,60612,78112,83912,97113,02312,968JulyAugSeptOctNovDec 3 .90,65091,48391,63991,89992,49895,00071,86272,64072,82973,07373,49174,70030,68030,91830,79330,85230,93731,00018,16518,39018,56418. 71418,94519,7003,7113,7553,7713,7703,7723,80019,30619, 57719,70119, 73719,83720,20018,78818,84318,81018,82619,00720,3005,8885,9735,9936.1076,1997.20012,90012,87012,81712.71912,80813,1001 Holdings <strong>of</strong> financial institutions only; holdings <strong>of</strong> retail outlets are included in "o<strong>the</strong>r consumer goodspaper."2 Single-payment loans and service credit.3 Preliminary; December by Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning January and August 1959, respectively.Source: Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System (except as noted).275


TABLE B-53.—Installment credit extended and repaid, 7946-66[Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year or monthTotalAutomobilepaperO<strong>the</strong>r consumergoods paperRepair andmodernizationloansPersonalloansExtendedRepaidExtendedRepaidExtendedRepaidExtendedRepaidExtendedRepaid19461947194819498,49512,71315,58518,1086,78510,19013,28415,5141,9693,6925,2176,9671,4432,7494,1235,4303,0774,4985,3835,8652,6033,6454,6255,0604237047147342003915793,8194,2714,5422,5393,4053,9574,3351950195119521953195421,55823,57629,51431, 55831,05118,44522,98525,40527,95630,4888,5308,95611,76412,98111,8077,0119,05810,00310,87911,8337,1507,4859,1869,2279,1176,0577,4047,8928,6229,1458358411,2171,3441,2617177729171,1191,2555,0436,2947,3478,0064,6605, 7516,5937,3368,2551955195619571958195938,97239,86842,01640,11948, 05233,63437,05439,86840,34442,60316,73415,51516,46514,22617,77913,08214, 55515,54515,41515, 57910,64211,72111,80711, 74713,9829, 75210, 75611,56911, 56312,4021,3931,5821,6741,8712,2221,3161,3701,4771,6261,76510,20311, 05112,06912,27514, 0709,48410,37311,27611,74112,8571960196119621963196449,56048,39655,12661,29567,50545,97247,70050,62055,17161,12117,65416,00719, 79622,29224,43516,38416,47217,47819,40021,67614,47014, 57815,68517,10219,47313,57414,24614,93915, 85017,7372,2132,0682,0512,1982,2041,8832,0151,9962,0382,07815,22315,74417.59419,70321,39314,13014,96716,20617, 88319,6301965196675, 50879,10067,49573,00027,91428,70024,26726, 50021,45423,40019,35521,4002,2382,2002,0962,10023,90224,80021, 77723,000Seasonally adjusted1965: Jan...Feb..Mar..Apr..May.June_5,9476,0826,1076,2456,1676,1965,3325,4855,4655,5005,5115,6012,1862,2492,2682,2992,2492,2851,9161,9471,9701,9751,9872,0071,6951,7681,7021,6481,7311,7191,5271,6651,5681,4971,5691,5901851771891941911991721731741801741791,8811,8881,9482,1041,9961,9931,7171,7001,7531,8481,7811,825July.Aug.Sept.Oct-.Nov.Dec.6,3836,3856,4346,4256,5306,4895,6595,7295,7485,8055,8315,8552,3552,3722,3852,3382,4802,4432,0072,0682,0562,0802,1482,1071,8181,8161,8591,9071,8731,8621,6081,6621,6381,6701,6831,7201801941761791851851711801711711761752,0302, 0032,0142,0011,9921,9991,8731,8191,8831,8841,8241,8531966: Jan..Feb..Mar.Apr..May.June.6,5446,4926,6736,5056,4726,6755,9475,9546,0245,9745,9796,1262,3402,3402,4792,3022,2982,4192,1152,1352,2162,1452,1592,2111,9831,9571,9591,9581,9331,9441,7781,7811,7081,7291,7841,7671761711831801861891761741761751721762, 0452,0242,0522,0652,0552,1231,8781,8641,9241,9251,8641,972July.Aug_Sept.Oct._Nov.Deci6,7326,6896,5786,5226,6576,7256,1686,0876,1036,1426,2136,3002,3832,4312,3872,3782,4612,4502,2382,2232,2132,2442,2552.2802,0501,9951,9581,9411,9471,9601,8031,7921,7841,8201,8361,8501891871751661661651741721681691691702,1102,0762,0582,0372,0832,1501,9531,9001,9381,9091,9532,000i Preliminary; December by Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning January and August 1959, respectively. Therefore,<strong>the</strong> difference between extensions and repayments for January and August 1959 and for <strong>the</strong> year 1959does not equal <strong>the</strong> net change in credit outstanding.Source: Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System (except as noted).276


TABLE B-54.—Mortgage debt outstanding, by type <strong>of</strong> property and oj financing, 1939-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars!Nonfarm propertiesEnd <strong>of</strong> year or quarterTotalTotal1- to 4-family housesAllpropertiesGovernment underwrittenTotalFHAinsuredVAguaranteedConventionaliMultifamilyandcommercialproperties2Farmproperties1939..1940..1941.1942..1943..1944..35.536.537.636.735.334.728.930.031.230.829.929.716.317.418.418.217.817.91.82.33.03.74.14.21.82.33.03.74.14.214.515.115.414.513.713.712.512.612.912.512.111.86.66.56.46.05.44.91945..1946..1947..1948..1949..35.541.848.956.262.730.836.943.950.957.118.623.028.233.337.64.3G.I9.312.515.04.13.73.85.36.90.22.45.57.28.114.316.918.920.822.612.213.815.717.619.54.84.95.15.35.61950...1951...1952...1953...1954...72.882.391.4101.3113.766.775.684.293.6105.445.251.758.566.175.718.922.925.428.132.18.69.710.812.012.810.313.214.616.119.326.328.833.138.043.621.623.925.727.529.76.16.77.27.78.21955..1956...1957...1958...1959...129.9144.5156.5171.8190.8120.9134.6146.1160.7178.788.299.0107.6117.7130.938.943.947.250.153.814.315.516.519.723.824.628.430.730.430.049.355.160.467.677.032.635.638.543.047.99.09.810.411.112.11960.1961.1962.1963.1964.1965.1966 p206.8226.3251.6281.2311.6341.7366.4194.0212.4236.4264.4292.7320.6343.0141.3153.1166.5182.2197.6213.5225.256.459.162.265.969.273.126.729.532.335.038.342.029.729.629.930.930.931.184.893.9104.3116.3128.3140.452.759.369.982.295.1107.0117.812.813.915.216.818.921.223.41963: IIll-IV.1964: I—.II..III-IV-257.1265.3273.4281.2287.4295.5303.6311.6241.6249.2256.8264.4270.0277.5285.1292.7169.2173.7178.2182.2185.4189.8193.9197.663.063.864.665.966.667.368.469.233.033.534.335.035.736.337.438.330.030.330.430.931.030.931.130.9106.2109.9113.6116.3118.8122.5125.4128.372.475.578.682.284.687.791.295.115.616.216.616.817.318.118.518.91965: IIII P..IV P..1966:UP...III p..IV P..317.7325.9333.9341.7348.2355.6361.4366.4298.3305.7313.2326.5333.1338.4343.0200.7205.2209.5213.5216.7220.5223.1225.270.170.772.073.174.174.675.339.039.740.942.043.043.744.431.131.031.131.131.130.930.9130.7134.4137.4140.4142.6145.8147.897.5100.5103.7107.0109.8112.7115.3117.819.520.220.721.221.822.523.023.41 Derived figures.2 Includes negligible amount <strong>of</strong> farm loans held by savings and loan associations.Source: Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System, estimated and compiled from data suppliedby various Government and private organizations.277


TABLE B-55.—Net public and private debt, 7929-66 ][BiUions <strong>of</strong> dollars]PrivateEnd <strong>of</strong>year *TotalFederalGovernmentandagencyTotalTotalCorporateTotalIndividual and noncorporateFarm 3TotalNonfarmStateandlocalgovernmentsLongtermShorttermMortgageCommercialandConsumercial*1929-...1930—.1931—.1932—.1933....1934—1935—1936—1937—.1938—1939—190.9191.0181.9174.6168.5171.4174.7180.3182.0179.6183.216.516.518.521.324.330.434.437.739.240.542.613.214.115.516.616.715.916.016.216.116.016.3161.2160.4147.9136.7127.5125.1124.2126.4126.7123.1124.388.989.383.580.076.975.574.876.175.873.373.547.351.150.349.247.944.643.642.543.544.844.441.638.233.230.829.130.931.233.532.328.429.272.371.164.456.750.649.649.450.350.949.850.812.211.811.110.19.18.98.98.68.69.08.860.159.353.346.641.540.640.541.742.340.942.031.232.030.929.026.325.524.824.424.324.525.022.421.617.614.011.711.210.811.211.310.19.86.45.84.83.63.53.94.96.16.76.37.21940—1941—1942-...1943—1944—1945—1946—1947—1948--.1949—1950--.-19511952—1953—19541955—19561957—1958--.1959--.-1960.--1961 —1962-_.1963—1964—189.9211.6259.0313.6370.8406.3397.4417.4433.6448.4490.3524.0555.2586.5612.0672.3707.5738.9782.6846.2890.2947.71,019.31,096. 91,174.31965.— 1,270.31966 «... 1,368.344.856.3101.7154.4211.9252.7229.7223.3216.5218.6218.7218.5222.9228.1230.2231.5225.4224.4232.7243.2241.0248.1255.8261.0267.2269.8274.616.516.315.814.914.113.713.614.416.218.120.723.325.828.633.438.442.746.750.955.660.065.073.779.585.295.1101.1128.6139.0141.5144.3144.8139.9154.1179.7200.9211.7250.9282.2306. 5329.8348.4402.5439.4467.8499.1547.4589.2634.6689.8756.4821.9905.4992.675.683.491.695.594.185.393.5108.9117.8118.0142.1162.5171.0179.5182.8212.1231.7246.7259.5283.3302.8324.3348.2376.1402.6445.6500.943.743.642.741.039.838.341.346.152.556.560.166.673.378.382.990.0100.1112.1121.2129.3139.1149.3161.2174.4189.2207.5235.531.939.849.054.554.347.052.262.865.361.581.995.997.7101.2100.0122.2131.7134.6138.4154.0163.6175.0187.0201.7213.4238.1265.453.055.649.948.850.754.660.670.883.193.7108.8119.7135.5150.3165.6190.4207.7221.1239.5264.1286.4310.3341.6380.3419.3459.8491.79.19.39.08.27.77.37.68.610.812.012.313.615.216.917.618.819.520.323.323.025.127.530.233.236.039.342.543.946.340.940.542.947.453.062.372.481.896.6106.2120.4133.6147.9171.6188.2200.8216.2241.1261.4282.8311.4347.1383.3420.5449.226.127.126.826.126.027.032.538.845.150.659.467.475.283.894.6108.7121.3131.6144.6160.8174.5190.4210.6234.3259.5284.8304.09.510.08.19.511.814.712.111.912.913.915.816.217.818.420.824.024.424.326.528.730.834.837.642.345.447.850.28.39.26.04.95.15.78.411.614.417.321.422.627.431.432.538.942.544.845.151.556.057.763.270.578.487.995.01 Net public and private debt outstanding is a comprehensive aggregate <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> indebtedness <strong>of</strong> borrowersafter elimination <strong>of</strong> certain types <strong>of</strong> duplicating governmental and corporate debt. For a fur<strong>the</strong>r explanation<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> concept, see Survey <strong>of</strong> Current Business, October 1950.2 Data for State and local government debt are for June 30.3 Farm mortgages and farm production loans. Farmers' financial and consumer debt is included in <strong>the</strong>nonfarm categories.4 Financial debt is debt owed to banks for purchasing or carrying securities, customers' debt to brokers,and debt owed to life insurance companies by policyholders.8 Estimate.NOTE.—Kevisions for 1929-39 and 1955-57 in <strong>the</strong> consumer credit data <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Federal Reserve System have not yet been fully incorporated into this series.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce (Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s), Treasury Department, Department<strong>of</strong> Agriculture, Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System, and Federal Home Loan Bank Board.278


GOVERNMENT FINANCETABLE B-56.—U.S. Government debt, by kind <strong>of</strong> obligation, 1929-66End <strong>of</strong> year or month1929193019311932 _1933 „19341935 —_ _19361937. .1938 _ _1939194019411942 __1943194419451946194719481949_ -195019511952—19531954195519561957-1958 _ _ __ .1959I960. >1961 _19621963—1964 _196519661965: JanFebMarAprMayJune _- -JulyAug.SeptOctNovDec1966* JanFebMarAprMayJuneJulyAugSeptOctNovDecGrosspublicdebt andguaranteedissues l[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Interest-bearing public debtMarketable public Nonmarketable public issuesissuesShorttermUnited TreasuryTreasury States tax and Investmentissues 2 bonds savings savingsbonds notes 3 bonds *16.316 017 820.824.031.535.139 141.944.447 650.964.3112.5170.1232.1278.7259.5257.0252.9257.2256.7259.5267.4275.2278.8280.8276.7275.0283.0290.9290.4296.5304.0310.1318.7321.4329.8318.6320.6318.4317.2319.8317.9317.1318.7317.3319.4322.2321.4322.4323.7321.5320.1322.8320.4319.8324.9325.2327.4329.9329.83.32 92 85 97.511 114.212 512 59.87 77.58.027.047.169.978 257.147.745.950.258.365.668.777.376.081.379 582.192.2103.5109.2120.5124.6121.2115.5110.4118.9111.6114.3112.0112.0108.5106.2106.2104.1104.1107.8110.4110.4113.5114.5112.0111.9111.8107.2107.2110.8111.3114.8118.1118.911.311.313.513.414.715.414.319.520.524.026.928.033.449.367.991.6120.4119.3117.9111.4104.894.076.979.877.281.881.980.882.183.484.879.875.578.486.497.0104.299.2102.8100.6100.5100.5102.5102.5102.5104.3104.3104.3104.2104.2104.2103.2103.1103.1102.0101.9101.9100.6100,5100.599.299.20.251.01.42 23.26.115.027.440.448.249.852.155.156.758.057.657.957.757.757.956.352.551.248.247.247.547.548.849.750.350.849.849.949.950.050.050.050.150.250.250.350.350.350.350.350.450.450.550.550.650.650.650.750.850.82.56.48 69.88 25.75.44.67.68.67.55.86.04.5tik|Enkkk1.01.01.01.013.013.412.912.712.311.610.39.07.66.25.14.43.73.42.82.73.43.33.33.33.33.33.33.33.22.82.82.82.82,82.82.72.72.72.72.72.72.72.72.7Specialissues s0.684.4.4.6.762.23.24 25.47.09.012.716.320.024.629.031.733.933.735.939.241.242.643.945.645.844.843.544.343.543.443.746.146.352.044.245.645.744.447.848.647.849.848.147.047,146.344.445.846.044.948.851.150.753.253.151.952.552.01 Total includes non-interest-bearing debt, fully guaranteed securities (except those held by <strong>the</strong> Treasury),Postal Savings bonds, prewar bonds, adjusted service bonds, depositary bonds, armed forces leavebonds, Rural Electrification Administration series bonds, foreign series certificates and notes, foreign currencycertificates, notes and bonds, Treasury certificates, and U.S. retirement plan bonds, not shown separately.Not all <strong>of</strong> total shown is subject to statutory debt limitation.2 Bills, certificates <strong>of</strong> indebtedness, and notes.3 The last series <strong>of</strong> Treasury savings notes matured in April 1956.4 Series A bonds through September 1965 and, beginning April 1951, series B convertible bonds.5 Issued to U.S. Government investment accounts. These accounts also held $16.4 billion <strong>of</strong> publicmarketable and nonmarketable issues on December 31,1966.Source: Treasury Department.279


TABLE B-57.—Estimated ownership <strong>of</strong> U.S. Government obligations, 1939-66End <strong>of</strong> year ormonth1939194019411942194319441945194619471948194919501951195219531954195519561957195819591960 -196119621963196419651966 8 -1965: Jan...Feb..Mar..Apr._May..June.July..Aug_.Sept..Oct_.Nov..Dec...1966: Jan...Feb..Mar-Apr..May..June~July-Aug..Sept-Oct—Nov..Dec 8 .Total47.650.964.3112.5170.1232.1278.7259.5257.0252.9257.2256.7259.5267.4275.2278.8280.8276.7275.0283.0290.9290.4296.5304.0310.1318.7321.4329.8318.6320.6318.4317.2319.8317.9317.1318.7317.3319.4322.2321.4322.4323.7321.5320.1322.8320.4319.8324.9325.2327.4329.9329.8Heldby U.S.Gov-6.57.69.512.216.921.727.030.934.437.339.439.242.345.948.349.651.754.055.254.453.755.154.555.658.060.661.968.859.160.460.759.262.763.462.364.863.662.362.861.960.061.761.760.564.566.766.469.369.268.068.968.8[Par values, 1 billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]HeldbyFederalReservebanksGross public debt and guaranteed issues 22.52.22.36.211.518.824.323.322.623.318.920.823.824.725.924.924.824.924.226.326.627.428.930.833.637.040.844.336.736.937.637.838.739.139.239.039.839.740.640.840.640.240.740.741.542.242.442.542.943.043.944.3Total38.641.152.594.0141.6191.6227.4205.2200.1192.2198.9196.8193.4196.9201.0204.2204.3197.8195.5202.3210.6207.9213.1217.6218.5221.1218.7216.8222.8223.3220.2220.3218.5215.4215.6214.9213.9217.5218.8218.7221.9221.9219.0218.9216.9211.5211.0213.1213.2216.42J7.1216.8ern-mentinvestmentaccountsCommercialbanks 315.917.321.441.159.977.790.874.568.762.566.861.861.663.463.769.262.059.559.567.560.362.167.267.264.364.000.857.162.961.760.459.758.458.357.256.457.459.659.860.860.958.757.057.055.154.753.454.754.454.955.157.1Held by "<strong>the</strong> public"Mutualsavings9.410.111.915.821.228.034.736.735.932.731.529.626.325.525.124.123.121.320.219.919.518.117.517.617.116.815.814.317.117.217.016.816.616.316.316.316.316.015.815.815.915.815.715.415.214.814.714.614.614.414.414.3banksand insurancecompaniesStateO<strong>the</strong>r andcorporations< governuals6local Individments52.22.04.010.116.421.422.215.314.114.816.819.720.719.921.519.123.218.717.718.121.418.718.518.618.717.915.514.918.619.017.217.017.615.115.916.114.715.616.715.516.517.415.715.716.213.914.214.313.514.916.014.90.4.5.71.02.14.36.56.37.37.98.18.89.611.112.714.415.416.316.616.518.018.719.020.121.121.222.923.822.223.023.224.324.424.124.023.723.023.322.922.923.724.724.425.125.324.524.824.624.224.224.123.810.110.613.623.737.653.364.164.265.765.566.364.665.264.863.565.065.964.963.769.466.165.966.068.270.072.375.670.671.071.571.271.271.171.871.872.272.272.372.373.273.574.674.374.173.974.174.875.876.275.975.6Miscellaneousinvestors70.7.7.92.34.47.09.18.18.48.99.410.510.611.713.213.915.616.116.616.622.124.225.028.029.231.231.431.131.531.430.831.330.230.530.430.530.230.831.431.431.831.831.631.430.929.729.830.130.631.731.531.11 United States savings bonds, series A-F and J, are included at current redemption value.2 Excludes guaranteed securities held by <strong>the</strong> Treasury. Not all <strong>of</strong> total shown is subject to statutory debtlimitation.3 Includes commercial banks, trust companies, and stock savings banks in <strong>the</strong> United States and Territoriesand island possessions; figures exclude securities held in trust departments. Since <strong>the</strong> estimates inthis table are on <strong>the</strong> basis <strong>of</strong> par values and include holdings <strong>of</strong> banks in United States Territories and possessions,<strong>the</strong>y do not agree with <strong>the</strong> estimates in Table B-49, which are based on book values and relate onlyto banks within <strong>the</strong> United States.4 Exclusive <strong>of</strong> banks and insurance companies.5 Includes trust, sinking, and investment funds <strong>of</strong> State and local governments and <strong>the</strong>ir agencies, and <strong>of</strong>Territories and possessions.6 Includes partnerships and personal trust accounts.7 Includes savings and loan associations, nonpr<strong>of</strong>it institutions, corporate pension trust funds, dealers andbrokers, and investments <strong>of</strong> foreign balances and international accounts in this country. Beginning withDecember 1946, <strong>the</strong> international accounts include investments by <strong>the</strong> International Bank for Reconstructionand Development, <strong>the</strong> International Monetary Fund, <strong>the</strong> International Development Association, <strong>the</strong>Inter-American Development Bank, and various United Nations' funds, in special non-interest-bearingnotes and bonds issued by <strong>the</strong> U.S. Government. Beginning with June 30, 1947, includes holdings <strong>of</strong>Federal land banks.8 Preliminary estimates by Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers.Source: Treasury Department (except as noted).280


TABLE B-58.—Average length and maturity distribution <strong>of</strong> marketable interest-bearingpublic debt, 1946-66End <strong>of</strong> year or monthAmountoutstandingWithin1 year1 to 5yearsMaturity class5 to 10years10 to 20years20 yearsandoverAverage lengthFiscal year:1946__._1947....1948...-1949...-189, 606168, 702160, 346155,14761, 97451,21148, 74248,130Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars24, 76321, 85121, 63032, 56241,80735, 56232, 26416, 74617, 46118, 59716, 22922, 82143, 59941,48141, 48134, 888YearsMonths1950...-1951...-1952...-1953....1954...-155,310137,917140, 407147, 335150, 35442, 33843, 90846,36765, 27062, 73451, 29246, 52647, 81436,16129, 8667,7928,70713, 93315, 65127, 51528, 03529, 97925,70028, 66228, 63425, 8538,7976,5941,5921,6068461955...-1956....1957..._1958...-1959....1960....1961...-1962....1963....1964....1965....1966.—1965: Jan_.Feb_.Mar_.Apr...May.June..July..Aug...Sept..Oct...Nov..Dec...1966: Jan...Feb._Mar..Apr._May.June..July..Aug...Sept..Oct...Nov_.Dec.155, 206154, 953155, 705166. 675178, 027183, 845187,148196, 072203, 508206, 489208, 695209,127214,411214,863212,507212,451210,954208,695208,664208,402208,381212,097214,619214,604217, 656217,690215,150215, 004213, 764209,127209,108211,402211,771215,313217,239218,02549, 70358, 71471, 95267, 78272, 95870,46781,12088,44285, 29481, 42487, 63789,13686,79889,82987,51788,12689,90187,63787,63592,44692,44496,49193,39293,39696,46194,22691, 70491, 82092, 231,89,13689,13892,23892,64296,656104,398105,21839,10734, 40140, 66942, 55758,30472, 84458, 40057, 04158, 02665, 45356,19860,93357,88659,70362,13561,48756,17856,19856,19255, 26655,26454,95260,59360,60260,60862, 89364,30664, 07662,45360,93360,93262,95762,95262,49559, 45959,44734, 25328, 90812, 32821, 47617, 05220, 24626, 43526,04937, 38534, 92939,16933,59643,90239,53237,12037,11639,17239,16939,16635,03235,02735,02435,02135,01335, 01335, 00833,60733,60333,60033, 59633,59230, 78330,77430, 77128,00828,00528, 61328, 57826, 40727, 65221, 62512, 63010. 2339,3198,3608,3558.4498,4396,1076,1066,1066,1068,4508,4498,4488,4488,4478,4468,4468,4458,4448,4438,4428,4418,4408,4398,4398,4378,4368,4358,4348,4333,5304,3514,3497,2087,65810, 96015, 22114, 44416, 32817, 24117, C2319,71819,69319,63019,61617,25317, 24117, 22217, 21017,19917,18417,16717,14817,13117,12017, 09217, 06517, 04017, 02317, 00716,98716,96716,95716,94016,92310493461110411544344333100101111101111101110887NOTE.—All issues classified to final maturity except partially tax-exempt bonds, which were classified toearliest call date (<strong>the</strong> last <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se bonds were called on Aug. 14,1962, for redemption on Dec. 15,1962).Source: Treasury Department.281


TABLE B-59.—Federal administrative budget receipts by source and expenditures by Junction,fiscal years 1939-68 1[Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Fiscalyear1939—1940—1941—1942—1943—1944—1945—1946—1947—1948—1949—.1950—1951—1952—1953—1954—1955—1956—.1957—1958—1959—1960—.1961—-1962—1963-1964—1965—1966—.1967« ...1968 5-Net receiptsTotal4,9795,1377,09612,54721,94743,56344,36239,65039,67741,37537,66336,42247,48061,28764,67164,42060,20967,85070,56268,55067,91577,76377J 65981,40986,37689,45993,-072104, 727116,995126,937Individualincometaxes1,0229591,4003,2056,49019,70118,41516,15717,83519,30515,54815,74521,64327,91330,10829,54228,74732,18835,62034,72436,71940,71541,33845,57147,58848,69748,79255,44662,20073,200Corporationincometaxes1,1381,1232,0294,7279,57014,73715,14611,8338,5699,67811,19510,44814,10621,22521,23821,10117,86120,88021,16720,07417,30921,49420,95420,52321,57923,49325,46130,07334,40033,900Excisetaxes1,8611,9732,5553,3934,0934,7616,2676,9997,2077,3567,5027,5498,6488,8519,8689,9459,1319,9299,0558,6128,5049,1379,0639,5859,91510,21110,9119,1459,3008,800Employmenttaxes12716511715416020018921331450235225234256274283579322328333321339Estateandgifttaxes3573574034214425076386697708907806987088188819349241,1611,3651,3931,3331,6061,8962,0162,1672,3942,7163,0663,1003,100Customs3023313653693084173414244774033674076095335965425856827357829251,1059821,1421,2051,2521,4421,7671,9802,100Miscellaneousreceipts1882372352869243,3133,4803,4764,6143,8072,0691,4221,6201,7941,8592,3092,5623,0032,7603,2003,1604,0624,0803,2064,4354,0764,6195,8656,7806,517Interfundtransactions-17-7-7-9-39-73-113-122-109-113-33-73-88-104-154-235-181-315-467-567-355-694-654-633-513-664-870-635-766-682ExpendituresTotal8,8419,05513,25534,03779,36894,98698,30360,32638,92332,95539,47439,54443,97065,30374,12067,53764,38966,22468,96671,36980,34276,53981,51587,78792,64297,68496,5J}7106,978126,729135,033Nationaldefense1,0751,4986,05423,97063,21676,75781,27743,22614,39811,77912,92613,01822,47144,03750,44246,98640,69540,72343,36844,23446,48345,69147,49451,10352,75554,18150,16357,71870,22275, 487Internationalaffairsandfinancea20511451,8393,2993,6423,3123,1076,5364,5666,0524,6743,7362,8262,2161,7322,3102,46723,5453,5594,9803,1954,1244,5234,4124,0324,5064,1914,6084,797See footnotes at end <strong>of</strong> table.282


TABLE B-59.—Federal administrative budget receipts by source and expenditures by function,fiscal years 1939-68 *—Continued[Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Expenditures—ContinuedFiscalyearSpaceresearchandtechnologyAgricultureandagriculturalresourcesNaturalresourcesCommerceandtransportationHousingand Health,com-labor,mu-nity welfareanddevelopmentEducationVeteransbenefitsandservicesInterestGeneralgovernmentAllowancesInterfundtransactions1,199360662-148415609503351940 _„1941._1942. .1943 _.1944..1,5381,3141,4826101,2154714525335014024545772,6007,2117,725351292153093163,0002,5361,9261,13288141434747945525665586067451,0561,1231,2721,8252,623370409515825989-14-101-933-236-4331945._1946._1947._1948. .1949. .323538491,6077471,2435752,5123193425487431,0574,1438866551,2181,618-185-19335694295864865,148,213,433154796268672,0954,4157,3816,6536,7253.6624,8165,0125,2485,445,047,353,263,054139955196-5012391950._1951..1952..1953..1954. .54626779902,7956761,0602,9492,564,206,275,375,4841,7591,6251,8881,9261,219268531593.,790,863,9162,0522,122781031913203266,6465,4004,9334,3684,3415,8175,7145,9346,5836,470,170,307,445,461,226267-793-961-154-2351955 __1956..1957..1958..1959 _.747176891454,2464,2342,9523,0665,354,216,125,320,587,7411,2251,8921,3051,6322,025136-10-118309702,1652,4622,6313,0423,8413773434375417324,5224,8104,8705,1845,2876,8467,3077,6897,671,166,576,738,284,466-181-315-467-567-355I960..1961._1962..1963. .1964.-4017441,2572,5524,1713,4753,4984,1165,0505,1291,7982,1002,2642,5062,6581,9632,5732,7742,8433,002122320349-67-803,6504,2004,4814,7155,3819431,0761,2441,3395,2665,4145,4035,1865,4929,2669,0509,19810, 7651,5421,7091,8751,9792,280-654-633-513-6641965.-1966 .1967*.1968«-5,0935,9335,6005,3004,6963,3073,0353,1732,8513,1203,2263,5183,4992,9693,4953,089-1043478901,0235,7977,57410,38911,3041,5442,8343,3042,8165,4955,0236,3946,12411,43512,13213,50814,1522,4022,4642,7252,781100«2,150-870—635-766-6821 For administrative budget surplus or deficit, see Table B-60.2 Beginning 1957, includes agricultural commodities donated abroad through voluntary agencies; classifiedunder "Agriculture and agricultural resources" in <strong>the</strong> earlier years.3 Beginning with 1952, includes watershed projects <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Soil Conservation Service; <strong>the</strong>se are classifiedunder "Agriculture and agricultural resources" in <strong>the</strong> earlier years.4 Includes adjustment to Daily Treasury Statement prior to 1953.s Estimate.6 Includes allowance <strong>of</strong> $1 billion for civilian and military pay increases, $750 million for possible shortfallin asset sales, and $400 million for contingencies.Sources: Treasury Department and Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Budget.283


TABLE B-60.—Federal administrative budget receipts and expenditures and <strong>the</strong> public debt y 1929-68[Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Fiscal or calendar yearNetreceipts lExpendituresSurplusordeficit (-)Publicdebt at end<strong>of</strong> year 2Fiscal year:19293,8613,12773419301931193219331934193519361937193819394,0583,1161,9241,9973,0153,7063,9974,9565,5884,9793,3203,5774,6594,5986,6456,4978,4227,7336,7658,841738-462-2,735-2,602-3,630-2,791-4,425-2,777-1,177-3,862194019411942194319441945194619471948 _.19495,1377,09612,54721,94743,56344,36239,65039,67741,37537,6639,05513,25534,03779,36894,98698,30360,32638,92332,95539,474-3,918-6,159-21,490-57,420-51,423-53,941-20,6767548,419-1,81119501951...._.1952..195319541955.......195619571958195936,42247,48061,28764,67164,42060,20967,85070,56268,55067,91539,54443,97065,30374,12067,53764,38966,22468,96671,36980,342-3,1223,510-4,017-9,449-3,117-4,1801,6261,596-2,819-12,42719601961196219631964196519661967 31968 3Calendar year1948194977,76377,65981,40986,37689,45993,072104,727116,995126,93740,80037,46476,53981,51587,78792,64297,68496.507106,978126,729135,03335,55941,0561,224-3,856-6,378-6,266-8,226-3,435—2,251-9, 734-8,0965,241-3,59219501951 _19521953195437,23552,87764,70563,65460,93837,65756,23670,54772,81164,622-422-3,358-5,842-9,157-3,6831955195619571958195963,11970,61671,74968,26272,73865,89171,15775,34979,778-2,7713,779592-7,088-7,040196019611962196319641965__-._.196679,51878,15784,70987,51688,69696,679110,80277,56584,46391,90794,18896,945101,378118,0781,953-6,306-7,199-6,672-8,248-4,699-7,2761 Gross receipts less refunds <strong>of</strong> receipts and transfers <strong>of</strong> tax receipts to <strong>the</strong> old-age and survivors insurancetrust fund, <strong>the</strong> disability insurance trust fund, <strong>the</strong> railroad retirement account, <strong>the</strong> unemployment trustfund, and <strong>the</strong> highway trust fund.2 Includes guaranteed issues except those held by <strong>the</strong> Treasury. The change in <strong>the</strong> public debt fromyear to year reflects not only <strong>the</strong> budget surplus or deficit but also changes in <strong>the</strong> Government's cashon hand, and <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> corporate debt and investment transactions by certain Government enterprises.3 Estimate.Sources: Treasury Department and Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Budget.284


TABLE B-61.—Government cash receipts from and payments to <strong>the</strong> public, 7946-68[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Total] FederaliState and local 2Fiscal or calendar yearCashreceiptsCashpaymentsExcess<strong>of</strong> receiptsor <strong>of</strong>paymentsCashreceiptsCashpaymentsExcess<strong>of</strong> receiptsor <strong>of</strong>paymentsCashreceiptsCashpaymentsExcess<strong>of</strong> receiptsor <strong>of</strong>paymentsFiscal year:19461947194819491950195119521953195454.255.659.457.257.972.188.493.695.270.247.549.956.361.465.288.798.695.6-16.08.19.4.8-3.56.9-.3-5.0-.543.543.545.441.640.953.468.071.571.661.736.936.540.643.145.868.076.871.9-18.26.68.91.0-2.27.6-5.3-.210.712.014.015.616.918.720.422.123.68.510.613.515.818.219.420.821.823.82.21.5.5-.2-1.3-.7-.4.3_ 219551956 -1957195819591960196119621963196492.9105.0112.7114.4116.3133.8138.8146.4158.6167.997.2101.3111.5118.0131.8132.5141.2152.7161.5171.3-4.33.71.2-3.5-15.61.3-2.5-6.3-2.9-3.467.877.182.181.981.795.197.2101.9109.7115.570.572.580.083.594.894.399.5107.7113.8120.3-2.74.52.1-1.6-13.1.8-2.3-5.8-4.0-4.825.127.930.632.534.638.741.544.648.952.426.728.831.534.537.138.241.745.047.751.0-1.6— 9-!9-2.0-2.5.6-.2-.51.21.4196519661967 41968 4 _. _.176.6196.3177.7197.5-1.1-1.2119.7134.5154.7168.1122.4137.8160.9172.4-2.7-3.3-6.2-4.356.961.855.359.71.62.1Calendar year:19461947-... _ _1948194952.757.259.857.750.850.651.659.71.96.68.1-2.041.444.344.941.341.438.636.942.6.15.78.0-1.311.312.914.816.39.412.014.717.01.9.9.1—.71950 -195119521953195419551956 _-_195719581959I960196119621963 _196419651966*60.278.892.693.192.897.8109.6116.2115.3123.9138.6141.0153.3162.9169.9183.0209.961.078.193.3100.195.099.9105.0116.4124.8132.8134.8148.4158.0166.5173.6185.9212.5-.8.7—.7-7.0-2.2-2.14.7—.2-9.5-8.93.7-7.4-4.8-3.6-3.7-3.0-2.642.459.371.370.268.671.480.384.581.787.698.397.9106.2112.6115.0123.4145.142.058.072.077.469.772.274.783.489.095.694.7104.7111.9117.2120.3127.9150.9.51.2-.6-7.2-1.1-.75.61.1-7.2-8.03.6-6.8—5.7-4.6-5.2-4.5-5.717.819.521.322.924.226.429.331.733.536.440.343.147.150.354.959.664.819.020.021.322.725.327.730.233.035.937.340.143.746.249.353.458.061.6-1.3-.5m 2-1.1-1.4-.9-1.3-2.3-.92-.5.91.11.61.63.21 For derivation <strong>of</strong> Federal cash receipts and payments, see Budget <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> United States Government for <strong>the</strong>Fiscal Year ending June 80, 1968, and Table B-64.2 Estimated by Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers from receipts and expenditures in <strong>the</strong> national incomeaccounts. Cash receipts consist <strong>of</strong> personal tax and nontax receipts, indirect business tax and nontaxaccruals, and corporate tax accruals adjusted to a collection basis. Cash payments are total expendituresless Federal grants-in-aid and less contributions for social insurance. (Federal grants-in-aid are <strong>the</strong>reforeexcluded from State and local receipts and payments and included only in Federal payments.) See TableB-62.3 Surplus <strong>of</strong> $49 million.4 Estimate.s Deficit <strong>of</strong> $13 million.Sources: Treasury Department, Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Budget, Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce (Office <strong>of</strong> Business<strong>Economic</strong>s), and Council <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Advisers.240-782 0—67- -19285


TABLE B-62.—Government receipts and expenditures in <strong>the</strong> national income and product accounts1929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Calendar year or quarter1929..1930..1931-1932..1933-1934..1935-1936-1937..1938-1939..1940..1941-1942..1943-1944..1945..1946..1947..1948..1949-1950.1951.1952.1953.1954.1955.1956.1957.1958.1959.I960.1961.1962.1963-1964-1965-1966Total government11.310.89.58.99.310.511.412.915.415.015.417.725.032.649.251.253.250.956.858.956.068.784.889.894.389.7100.4109.0115.6114.7128.9139.8144.6157.0168.8174.2189.0«212.210.311.112.410.610.712.913.416.115.016.817.618.428.864.093.3103.092.745.542.450.359.160.879.093.7101.296.797.6104.1114.9127.2131.0136.1149.0159.9166.9175.6185.8208.71.0-.3-2.9-1.8-1.4-2.4-2.0-3.1.3-1.8-2.2-.7-3.8-31.4-44.1-51.8-39.55.414.48.5-3.27.85.8-3.8-6.9-7.02.74.9.7-12.5-2.13.7-4.3-2.91.8-1.43.23.5Federal Government 13.83.02.01.72.73.54.05.07.06.56.78.615.422.939.341.042.539.143.243.338.949.964.067.270.063.872.177.681.678.789.796.598.3106.4114.5115.1124.94 142. 42.62.84.23.24.06.46.58.77.48.68.910.020.556.185.895.584.635.629.834.941.340.857.871.077.069.768.171.979.688.991.093.0102.1110.3113.9118.1123.4142.2ReceiptsExpendituresSurplusordeficit(-), nationalincomeandproductaccountsReceiptsExpendituresState and localgovernmentSurplusordeficit(-), nationalReceiptpendi-Ex-incomeand turesproductaccounts1.2 7.6 7.8.3 7.8 8.4—2 1 7.7 8.5-L5 7.3 7.6-1.3 7.2 7.2-2.9 8.6 8.1-2.6 9.1 8.6-3.6 8.6 8.1-.4 9.1 8.4-2.1 9.3 9.0-2.2 9.6 9.6-1.3 10.0 9.3-5.1 10.4 9.1-33.1 10.6 8.8-46.6 10.9 8.4-54.5 11.1 8.5-42.1 11.6 9.03.5 12.9 11.013.4 15.3 14.38.4 17.6 17.4-2.4 19.3 20.09.1 21.1 22.36.2 23.3 23.7-3.8 25.2 25.3-7.0 27.2 27.0-5.9 28.8 29.94.0 31.4 32.75.7 34.7 35.62.1 38.2 39.5-10.2 41.6 44.0-1.2 46.0 46.83.5 49.9 49.6-3.8 53.6 54.1-3.857.6.762.2-3.067.91.6 75.3.2 4 84. 373.781.0Seasonally adjusted annual rates1964: I—II..III.IV.1965:II...III..IV..1966: IIIIIIIV P._172.3170.8175.4178.3186.5188.5188.6192.6203.1209.5215.9173.2176.5176.2176.2180.1182.4189.6191.2198.4202.2212.5221.6-0.9-5.7-.82.16.46.1-1.01.44.77.33.3115.3112.3115.4117.2124.0125.0123.8126.9136.0141.0145.3117.2119.1118.4117.7119.6120.6126.3127.0133.7137.1145.8152.2-1.9-6.7-3.0-.54.54.4-2.5_ 22.33.8-.566.868.770.872.073.474.675.977.380.183.285.965.767.668.669.571.572.974.475.777.779.782.184.71 See Note, Table B-63.2 Surplus <strong>of</strong> $32 million,a Deficit <strong>of</strong> $41 million.4 Data for corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its are.approximations for <strong>the</strong> year as a whole; data for fourth quarter are notavailable. All o<strong>the</strong>r data incorporating or derived from <strong>the</strong>se figuresare correspondingly approximate.NOTE.—Federal grants-in-aid to State and local governments are reflected in Federal expenditures andState and local receipts and expenditures. Total government receipts and expenditures have been adjustedto eliminate this duplication.Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.286


TABLE B-63.—Federal Government receipts and expenditures in <strong>the</strong> national income andproduct accounts, 1946-68[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year or quarter TotalFiscal year:194619471948194919501951195219531954195519561957195819591960196119621963196419651967119681Calendar year:194619471948194919501951195219531954195519561957195819591960196119621963196419651966 PCalendarquarter:1964: IIII1965: IIIIIIIV1966: III38.442.743.640.042.060.865.169.365.867.275.880.777.985.494.895.3104.2110.2115.5120.6132.6149.8167.139.143.243.338.949.964.067.270.063.872.177.681.678.789.796.598.3106.4114.5115.1124.9142.4115.3112.3115.4117.2124.0125.0123.8126.9136.0141.0145.3Personaltaxandnon-+ LdX QYceipts16.918.820.016.316.523.228.831.430.329.733.636.736.338.242.543.647.349.650.751.357.965.576.817.219.619.016.118.126.131.032.229.031.435.237.436.839.943.644.748.651.548.654.261.950.446.248.149.653.454.953.854.757.160.763.965.8ReceiptsCorporatepr<strong>of</strong>itstaxac-8.310.611.211.011.921.519.319.717.318.721.120.617.821.522.320.322.923.525.627.830.732.335.38.610.711.89.817.021.518.519.517.020.620.620.218.022.521.721.822.724.626.529.1231.526.026.426.826.728.728.728.930.331.931.931.6crualsIndirectbusinesstaxand7 47.97.98.08.29.59.710.710.410.010.811.711.611.913.213.314.215.015.616.915.916.516.97.87.88.08.08.99.410.310.99.710.711.211.811.512.513.513.614.615.316.216.816.015.516.116.616.517.516.816.316.715.216.116.216.55.85.54.64.85.56.67.37.57.88.710.211.712.213.816.718.119.922.123.624.628.135.538.1Total55.529.530.939.642.444.666.075.874.267.369.876.083.190.991.398.0106.4111.4116.9118.3132.3153.6169.2nontaxaccrualsContributionsforsocialinsurancePurchases<strong>of</strong>goodsandservices40.113.013.219.319.025.146.656.153.243.945.247.750.754.752.755.560.963.465.764.371.783.691.9ExpendituresTransferpaymentsTopersons8.38.78.111.38.18.59.310.512.112.814.417.819.820.623.625.126.427.328.232.037.444.0T<strong>of</strong>oreigners(net)1.82.65.04.33.12.62.11.72.11.81.91.71.81.82.12.12.12.22.22.32.42.65.5 35.6 17.2 9.2 2.25.1 29.8 12.5 8.8 1.94.5 34.9 16.5 7.6 3.84.9 41.3 20.1 8.7 5.15.9 40.8 18.4 10.8 3.67.1 57.8 37.7 8.5 3.17.4 71.0 51.8 8.8 2.17.4 77.0 57.0 9.5 2.08.1 69.7 47.4 11.5 1.89.3 68.1 44.1 12.4 2.010.6 71.9 45.6 13.4 1.912.2 79.6 49.5 15.7 1.812.4 88.9 53.6 19.5 1.814.8 91.0 53.7 20.1 1.817.7 93.0 53.5 21.5 1.918.2 102.1 57.4 24.9 2.120.5 110.3 63.4 25.5 2.223.1 113.9 64.2 27.0 2.223.9 118.1 65.2 27.8 2.224.8 123.4 66.8 30.3 2.233.0 142.2 77.0 34.2 2.3Seasonally adjusted annual rates23.423.724.024.424.524.624.725.231.732.233.634.3117.2119.1118.4117.7119.6120.6126.3127.0133.7137.1145.8152.264.966.665.164.164.465.667.569.871.974.079.082.528.327.527.627.729.228.432.530.832.632.634.537.22.22.32.22.12.02.52.21.92.82.22.42.0Grantsin-aidto Stateandlocalgovernments0.91.51.82.12.42.42.52.82.93.03.23.74.76.26.86.97.68.49.810.912.914.816.71.11.72.02.22.32.52.62.82.93.13.34.25.66.86.57.28.09.110.411.214.610.210.811.011.011.111.111.613.014.615.315.3Netinterestpaid3.74.24.24.34.44.64.84.85.04.95.15.55.75.97.06.86.87.58.18.59.110.010.54.24.24.34.44.54.74.74.95.04.95.35.75.66.47.16.67.27.78.38.79.68.28.28.48.48.68.78.88.89.39.59.710.0SurplusSubsidiesdefi-orcitless (-),currention-na-surplusinal<strong>of</strong> comegovernmentprod-anductenterprisesaccounts2.1.7.5.81.01.31.1.91.01.31.72.82.52.42.33.23.83.63.84.14.55.43.51.6.6.7.81.21.31.0.81.11.52.42.62.72.12.53.84.03.64.24.24.64.04.24.44.44.34.24.14.14.14.24.85.2-17.113.212.7.4-.516.2-1.0-6.5-8.5-.16.04.7-5.1-5.53.5-2.7-2.1-1.2-1.42.3.3-3.8-2.13.513.48.4-2.49.16.2-3.8-7.0-5.94.05.72.1-10.2-1.23.5-3.8-3.8.7-3.01.62.2-1.9-6.7-3.0-.54.54.4-2.5-.22.33.8-.51 Estimate.2 Data for corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its are approximations for <strong>the</strong> year as a whole; data for fourth quarter are not available.All o<strong>the</strong>r data incorporating or derived from <strong>the</strong>se figuresare correspondingly approximate.NOTE.—These accounts, like <strong>the</strong> cash budget, include <strong>the</strong> transactions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> trust accounts. Unlikeboth <strong>the</strong> administrative budget and <strong>the</strong> cash statement, <strong>the</strong>y exclude certain financial transactions. Ingeneral, <strong>the</strong>y do not use <strong>the</strong> cash basis for transactions with business. Instead, corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its taxesare included in receipts on an accrual instead <strong>of</strong> a cash basis; expenditures are timed with <strong>the</strong> delivery instead<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> payment for goods and services; and CCC guaranteed price-support crop loans financedby banks are counted as expenditures when <strong>the</strong> loans are made, not when CCC redeems <strong>the</strong>m.Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1960.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce (Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s) and Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Budget.287


TABLE B-64.—Relation <strong>of</strong> three measures <strong>of</strong> Federal Government receipts and expenditures,fiscal years, 1964-68•*[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Receipts or expendituresFiscal years1964 1965 1966 1967 2 1968RECEIPTSAdministrative budget receiptsPlus: Trust fund receiptsLess: Intragovernmental transactionsReceipts from exercise <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> monetary authorityEquals: Federal receipts from <strong>the</strong> publicLess:Exclusions from <strong>the</strong> Federal sector, national income89.530.34.2.1115.593.131.04.3.1119.7104.734.94.5.6134.5117.044.96.21.1154.7126.948.16.5.5168.1accounts:Loans repaid. __Items classified in ano<strong>the</strong>r sector:District <strong>of</strong> ColumbiaForeign assistance, military trustPlus:Exclusions from Federal receipts from <strong>the</strong> public:Excess <strong>of</strong> accruals over collectionsEmployer/employee contributions to Federal retirementfundsPlus:Miscellaneous retting, grossing, and related adjust-.72.01.12.2.3-1.22.3.4.31.1-3.92.3.41.4.42.3ments:Receipts netted against expenditures, etcO<strong>the</strong>rEquals: Federal receipts, national income and product accounts.-1.2-.1115.5-.7-.2120.6-1.2-.5132.6-1.0-.5149.8-1.0-.7167.1EXPENDITURESAdministrative budget expendituresPlus: Trust fund expenditures 3 ...Less: Intragovernmental transactionsDebt issued in lieu <strong>of</strong> checks and o<strong>the</strong>r adjustments..Equals: Federal payments to <strong>the</strong> publicLess: Exclusions from <strong>the</strong> Federal sector:Loans and financial transactions:Lending: NetFederal land banks and Federal home loan banks..Acquisition <strong>of</strong> foreign currency for financing agriculturalexportsItems classified in o<strong>the</strong>r sectors:District <strong>of</strong> ColumbiaForeign assistance, military trustPlus: Exclusions from Federal payments to public:Excess <strong>of</strong> deliveries or accruals over paymentsEmployer/employee contributions to Federal retirementfundsPlus: Miscellaneous netting, grossing, and related adjustments:Receipts netted against expendituresO<strong>the</strong>rEquals: Federal expenditures, national income and productaccounts97.728.94.22.0120.32.01.81.1.52.0-1.21.1116.996.529.64.3-.6122.43.31.21.22.2-.7.5118.3107.034.94.5-.4137.83.21.91.02.3-1.21.0132.3126.740.96.2.6160.94.31.71.1.51.1.22.3-1.0153.6135.044.56.5.7172.41.8.21.0.61.4.42.3-1.0.1169.2* The Federal sector receipts and expenditures are identical to those published by <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong>Commerce in <strong>the</strong> Survey <strong>of</strong> Current Business.2 Data for 1967 and 1968 are estimates.3 Includes Government sponsored enterprises, net.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included.Sources: Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Budget and Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce (Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s).288


TABLE B-65.—State and local government revenues and expenditures, selected fiscal years, 1927-65[Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]General revenues by source 2General expenditures by function *Fiscal year 1andgrossreceiptstaxesincometaxesIndividualCorporationnetincometaxesRevenuefromFederalGovernmentAllo<strong>the</strong>rrevenue3TotalEducationHigh-PublicwelfareAllo<strong>the</strong>r«1927193219341936193819401942194419461948...19501952195319541955195619571958195919601961196219631962-63 51963-64 51964-65 57,2717,2677,6788,3959,22810, 41810,90812, 35617, 25020,91125,18127, 30729, 01231, 07334, 66738,16441, 21945,30650, 50554, 03758,25262,89068, 44374,3414,7301,487t, 076t, 093[,440t, 430[,5374,6044,9866,1267,3498,6529,3759,96710, 73511, 74912, 86414,04714, 98316,40518,00219, 05420, 08919,83321, 24122,9184707521,0081,4841,7941,9822,3512,2892,9864,4425,1546,3576,9277,2767,6438,6919,4679,82910,43711, 84912, 46313,49414, 45614, 44615, 76217,1187074801532182242763424225437889981,0651,1271,2371,5381,7541,7591,9942,4632,6133,0373,2693,2673,7914,0909279491131651562724514475925938468177787448909841,0181,0011,1801,2661,3081,5051,5051,6951,9291162321,0169488009458589548551,8612,4862,5662,8702,9663,1313,3353,8434,8656,3776,9547,1317,8718,72210,00211,0291,7931,6431,4491,6041,8111,8722,1232,2692,6613,6854,5415,7636,2526,8977,5848,4659,2529,69910, 51611,63412,56313,48914,85014, 55515, 95217,2577,2107,7657,1817,6448,7579,2299,1908,86311,02817, 68422, 78726,09827, 91030, 70133, 72436, 71140, 37544,85148, 88751, 87656, 20160,20664, 81663,97769,30274, 7862,2352,3111,8312,1772,4912,6382,5862,7933,3565,3797,1778,3189,39010, 55711, 90713, 22014,13415, 91917, 28318, 71920, 57422, 21623, 77623, 72926, 28628,8031,8091,7411,5091,4251,6501,5731,4901,2001,6723,0363,8034 ;6504,9875, 5276,4526,9537,8168,5679,5929,4289,84410,35711,13611,15011, 66412,2211514448898271,1561,2251,1331,4092,0992,9402,7882,9143,0603,1683,1393,4853,8184,1364,4044,7205,0845,4815,4205,7666,3153,0153,2692,9523,2153,5473,8623,8893,7374,5917,1708,86710,34210, 61911, 55712,19713,39914,94016,54717, 87619, 32421,06322, 54924, 42323, 67825, 58627,4471 2 Fiscal years not <strong>the</strong> same for all governments. See footnote 5.Excludes revenues or expenditures <strong>of</strong> publicly owned utilities and liquor stores, and <strong>of</strong> insurance-trustactivities. Intergovernmental receipts and payments between State and local governments are alsoexcluded.34 Includes licenses and o<strong>the</strong>r taxes and charges and miscellaneous revenues.Includes expenditures for health, hospitals, police, local fire protection, natural resources, sanitation,housing and urban renewal, local parks and recreation, general control, financial administration, intereston 5 general debt, and o<strong>the</strong>r unallocable expenditures.Data for fiscal year ending in <strong>the</strong> 12-month period through June 30. Data for 1963 and earlier yearsinclude local government amounts grouped in terms <strong>of</strong> fiscalyears ended during <strong>the</strong> particular calendaryear.NOTE.—Data are not available for intervening years.Data for Alaska and Hawaii included beginning 1959 and 1960, respectively.See Table B-55 for net debt <strong>of</strong> State and local governments.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Census.289


Year orquarterCORPORATE PROFITS AND FINANCETABLE B-66.—Pr<strong>of</strong>its before and after taxes, all private corporations, 1929-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its (before taxes) andinventory valuation adjustmentManufacturingTotalAllindustriesDurablegoodsindustriesNondurablegoodsindustriesTransportation,communication,andpublicutilitiesAllo<strong>the</strong>rindustriesCorporatepr<strong>of</strong>itsbeforetaxesCorporatetaxliabilityiCorporate pr<strong>of</strong>itsafter taxesDividendTotalpaymentsUndistributedpr<strong>of</strong>itsCorporatecapitalconsumptionallowances2Pr<strong>of</strong>itspluscapitalconsumptionallowances'192910.55.22.62.61.83.410.01.48.65.82.84.212.81930193119321933193419351936-1937193819391940194119421943.1944194519461947194819497.02.0-1.3-1.21.73.45.66.84.96.39.815.220.324.423.819.219.325.633.030.83.91.3-.5-.41.12.13.23.82.33.35.59.511.813.813.29.79.013.617.616.21.5*-1.0-.4.3.91.71.7.81.73.16.47.28.17.44.52.45.87.58.12.41.3.5*.81.11.52.11.61.72.43.14.65.75.95.26.67.810.08.11.2.5.2.4.4.7.8.51.01.32.03.44.43.92.71.82.23.03.01.9.2-.9-.8.3.91.72.22.12.03.03.75.16.26.76.78.59.912.511.63.7-.4-2.31.02.33.66.36.84.07.010.017.721.525.124.119.724.631.535.228.9.8.5.4.5.71.01.41.51.01.42.87.611.414.112.910.79.111.312.510.42.9-.9-2.7.41.62.64.95.32.95.67.210.110.111.111.29.015.520.222.718.55.54.12.52.02.62.84.54.73.23.84.04.44.34.44.64.65.66.37.07.2-2.6-4.9-5.2-1.6-1.0-.2.4.6-.21.83.25.75.96.66.54.49.913.915.611.34.34.34.03.83.63.63.63.63.73.73.84.25.05.46.16.44.75.87.07.97.23.51.34.25.26.38.58.96.69.311.014.415.216.417.215.420.226.029.726.5195019511952—195319541955 -195619571958—195937.742.739.939.638.046.946.145.641.151.720.924.621.622.019.926.024.724.019.326.312.013.211.711.910.514.312.813.39.313.68.911.49.910.19.411.811.910.710.012.74.04.64.95.04.75.65.95.85.97.012.713.513.312.613.415.215.615.815.918.442.643.938.940.638.348.648.847.241.452.117.822.319.420.317.721.621.721.219.023.724.921.619.620.420.627.027.226.022.328.58.88.68.68.99.310.511.311.711.612.616.013.011.011.511.316.515.914.210.815.98.810.311.513.215.017.418.920.822.023.533.731.831.033.535.544.446.146.844.352.01960196119621963196419651966* .49.950.355.758.966.674.279.824.423.326.628.832.437.840.712.011.414.115.817.922.123.512.411.912.513.014.515.717.27.57.98.59.510.411.112.017.919.120.520.623.825.327.149.750.355.459.467.075.781.823.023.124.226.328.431.233.726.727.231.233.138.744.548.113.413.815.216.517.319.220.913.213.516.016.621.325.327.124.926.230.131.833.936.338.851.653.561.364.872.580.886.8Seasonally adjusted annual rates1964: IIIIII65.366.567.866.832.132.433.032.218.117.718.417.514.114.614.614.710.110.210.610.523.023.924.224.)65.866.867.867.727.928.328.728.638.038.539.139.017.117.317.417.720.921.321.721.432.933.534.234.870.972.073.373.91965: IIIIIIIV73.272.774.076.937.436.737.439.621.921.221.923.215.515.515.516.410.710.911.211.525.125.125.325.874.574.575.078.730.730.730.932.443.843.844.146.318.118.819.520.225.725.024.626.135.236.036.837.279.079.880.983.51966: IIIIIIIV J>80.079.979.141.940.639.524.723.422.517.217.217.011.312.012.226.727.227.482.782.881.934.134.133.748.748.748.220.921.121.120.727.827.627.137.738.539.139.786.487.187.31 Federal and State corporate income and excess pr<strong>of</strong>its taxes,a Includes depreciation and accidental damages.3 Corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its after taxes plus corporate capital consumption allowances.4 Data for corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its are approximations for <strong>the</strong> year as a whole; data for fourth quarter are notavailable. All o<strong>the</strong>r data incorporating or derived from <strong>the</strong>se figures are correspondingly approximate.NOTE.—Beginning 1962 data reflect <strong>the</strong> new depreciation guidelines issued by <strong>the</strong> Treasury DepartmentJuly 11,1962, and <strong>the</strong> investment tax credit provided in <strong>the</strong> Revenue Act <strong>of</strong> 1962.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.290


TABLE B—67.—Sales, pr<strong>of</strong>its, and stockholders* equity, all manufacturing corporations (exceptnewspapers), 7947—66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]All manufacturingcorporationsDurable goods industriesNondurable goodsindustriesYear orquarterPr<strong>of</strong>itsSales(net)BeforetaxesAftertaxesStockholders'equity »Sales(net)BeforetaxesPr<strong>of</strong>itsAftertaxesStockholdersequity :Sales(net)BeforetaxesPr<strong>of</strong>itsAftertaxesStockholders'equity l1947-1948-1949-1950-1951-1952-1953-1954-1955-1956-1957-1958-1959-1960-1961-1962-1963-1964-1965..150.7165.6154.9181.9245.0250.2265.9248.5278.4307.3320. 0305.3338.0345.7356.4389.9412.7443.1492.216.618.414.423.227.422.924.420.928.629.828.222.729.727.527.531.934.939.646.510.111.59.012.911.910.711.311.215.116.215.412.716.315.215.317.719.523.227.565.172.277.698.3103.7108.2113.1120.1131.6141.1147.4157.1165.4172.6181.4189.7199.8211.766.675.370.386.8116.8122.0137.9122.8142.1159.5166.0148.6169.4173.9175.2195.5209.0226.3257.07.68.97.512.915.412.914.011.416.516.515.811.415.814.013.616.718.521.226.24.55.44.56.76.15.55.85.68.18.37.95.88.17.06.98.69.511.614.531.134.137.047.249.852.454.958.865.270.572.877.982.384.989.193.398.5105.484.190.484.695.1128.1128.0128.0125.7136.3147.8154.1156.7168.5171.8181.2194.4203.6216.8235.29.09.57.010.312.110.010.412.113.212.411.313.913.513.91S.116.418.320.35.66.24.66.15.75.25.55.67.07.87.56.98.38.28.59.210.011.613.034.038.140.643.551.153.955.758.261.366.470.674.679.283.187.792.396.3101.3106.31964: IIIIIIV1965: IIIIIV1966: III—_III104.6111.9110.2116.5114.9124.0121.5131.9129.9141.0137.89.010.69.610.310.712.311.012.512.414.012.35.16.15.76.36.27.26.67.57.28.47.4195.2198.5201.7203.6205.4209.7213.6218.1222.4228.6233.453.358.655.259.260.066.062.069.068.075.471.14.96.14.85.46.17.25.87.17.08.26.52.53.32.73.14.03.34.03.84.63.796.297.999.5100.4102.2104.6106.4108.2110.0114.2117.151.353.354.957.354.958.059.462.961.965.666.74.14.64.84.94.65.15.25.45.45.85.82.62.93.03.22.93.23.33.53.43.73.799.1100.6102.2103.2103.2105.1107.2109.9112.4114.3116.3i Annual data are average equity for <strong>the</strong> year (using four end-<strong>of</strong>-quarter figures).NOTE.—For explanatory notes concerning compilation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> series, see Quarterly Financial <strong>Report</strong> forManufacturing Corporations, Federal Trade Commission and Securities and Exchange Commission.Data are not necessarily comparable from one period to ano<strong>the</strong>r due to changes in accounting procedures,industry classifications, sampling procedures, etc. Specific information about <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> moresignificant changes and revisions is contained in <strong>the</strong> following issues <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Quarterly Financial <strong>Report</strong>:third quarter 1953, third quarter 1956, first quarter 1959, and first quarter 1965.Comparability for certain industries was affected by changes noted in <strong>the</strong> following reports: fourthquarter 1952, first quarter 1955, second quarter 1960, third quarter 1960, fourth quarter 1965, and secondquarter 1966.Data for Alaska and Hawaii included for all periods.Sources: Federal Trade Commission and Securities and Exchange Commission.291


TABLE B-68.—Relation <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its after taxes to stockholders' equity and to sales, all manufacturingcorporations {except newspapers), by industry group, 1947-66Year orquarter19471948194919501951.195219531954195519561957195819591960196119621963196419651965:1966:194719481949195019511952195319541955.1956195719581959.19601961.1962196319641965.1965:1966:IIIIIIIVI.IIIIIIIIIllIVIIIIllAllmanufacturingcorporations(exceptnewspapers)15.616.011.615.412.110.310.59.912.612.310.98.610.49.28.99.810.311.613.012.113.812.313.713.014.712.76.77.05.87.14.84.34.34.55.45.34.84.24.84.44.34.54.75.25.65.45.85.45.75.65.95.4Durable goods industriesTotaldurableMotorvehiclesandequipmentAircraftandpartsElectricalmachinery,equipmentandsuppliesMachinery(exceptelectrical)FabricatedmetalproductsPrimaryironandsteelindustriesPrimarynonferrousmetalindustriesStone,clay.andglassproductsFurnitureandfixturesLumberandwoodproducts(exceptfurniture)InstrumentsandrelatedproductsRatio <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its after Federal taxes (annual rate) to stockholders' equity—percent14.415.712.116.913.011.111.110.313.812.811.38.010.48.58.19.610.111.713.812.915.312.414.614.016.212.66.77.16.47.75.34.54.24.65.75.24.83.94.84.03.94.44.55.15.75.56.15.35.75.66.25.216.419.922.125.314.313.913.914.121.713.114.28.214.513.511.416.316.716.919.522.923.510.321.420.619.75.56.06.97.98.34.74.73.95.16.35.25.44.06.35.95.56.96.97.07.28.18.24.87.37.37.12.817.713.28.17.39.812.711.312.215.212.214.716.417.214.615.912.719.016.113.620.914.013.713.112.412.311 412.510.212.59.58.910.010.111.213.511.713.113.216.014.315.514.615.716.311.614.113.011.39.88.610.312.610.76.99.77.57.89.19.612.514.112.015.814.414.314.417.014.817.617.010.416.013.410.1*9.87.610.010.79.37.38.05.65.97.98.310.113.211.315.014.112.513.916.615.612.014.710.014.312.38.510.78.113.512.711.47.28.07.26.15.47.08.89.811.011.58.67.99.112.29.712.414.28.115.113.811.611.110.415.516.49.36.07.97.17.17.57.69.811.911.813.310.412.214.016.213.614.015.013.117.714.211.711.812.515.614.912.410.212.79.98.98.98.79.610.34.612.113.510.85.912.912.3Pr<strong>of</strong>its after taxes per dollar <strong>of</strong> sales—cents2.92.41.61.41.82.42.32.63.32.73.13.63.53.13.22.76.35.95.77.25.04.54.14.54.43.84.23.84.43.53.53.73.84.24.84.34.64.75.24.85.14.97.27.36.47.35.54.84.24.45.15.44.83.74.83.94.14.54.75.86.25.76.66.36.16.36.96.47.47.15.16.85.04.03.63.13.84.03.63.13.22.42.53.13.23.74.54.25.14.84.14.85.35.16.67.66.57.95.84.75.35.37.26.76.65.45.45.14.63.94.85.65.76.26.25.25.25.46.45.48.99.06.910.27.86.76.36.68.39.36.64.75.85.45.35.55.36.57.37.67.76.77.38.08.57.77.98.68.610.17.16.66.57.48.68.27.56.87.96.65.85.65.35.65.93.16.77.26.03.96.86.518.015.98.115.211.38.68.26.09.211.68.56.38.96.54.97.98.310.113.49.813.014.516.012.415.914.56.05.53.35.13.42.72.62.12.93.42.62.02.72.11.62.32.42.93.72.93.74.04.23.64.23.922.919.29.117.511.98.57.16.311.18.74.75.79.43.64.15.68.29.910.16.710.712.710.18.114.611.211.49.95.99.45.54.13.53.45.43.92.32.84.21.71.92.53.33.94.02.94.24.73.93.35.24.114.414.012.116.713.211.611.412.312.512.412.010.613.111.610.612.012.114.417.514.716.017.721.517.620.522.07.77.87.18.66.14.84.65.56.05.85.75.46.55.95.45.96.07.28.67.88.09.09.58.59.310.1Miscellaneousmanufacturing(includingordnance)14.012.27.212.39.77.08.27.58.511.67.78.29.39.29.99.48.89.510.78.710.59.414.112.213.415.76.35.63.65.63.72.72.92.83.13.62.53.03.53.53.63.43.33.63.83.63.93.44.14.24.25.1See footnotes at end <strong>of</strong> table.292


TABLE B-68.—Relation <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its after taxes to stockholders' equity and to sales, all manufacturingcorporations {except newspapers), by industry group, 1947-66—ContinuedNondurable goods industriesYear or quarterTotalnondurable^FoodandkindredproductsTobaccomanufacturesTextilemillproductsApparelandrelatedproductsPaperandalliedproductsPrintingandpublishing(exceptnewspapers)ChemicalsandalliedproductsPetroleumrefiningRubberandmiscellaneousplasticproductsLea<strong>the</strong>randlea<strong>the</strong>rproductsRatio <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its after Federal taxes {annual rate) to stockholders* equity—percent*19471948194916.616.211.217.612.811.810.113.612.619.518.77.618.912.17.522.016.410.717.214.711.415.915.813.212.412.38.714.010.46.2195019511952195319541955 —1956... _.1957 _19581959 -14.111.29.79.99.611.411.810.69.210.412.38.17.68.18.18.99.38.78.79.311.59.58.49.410.211.411.712.513.513.412.78.24.24.61.85.75.84.23.57.510.12.94.45.14.56.18.16.34.98.616.213.910.510.19.911.511.68.98.19.511.510.39.19.49.210.213.011.79.011.417.812.210.910.711.614.714.213.311.413.715.213.313.412.713.413.912.510.09.816.914.811.111.310.613.212.211.19.111.010.92.15.86.05.98.57.27.05.78.51960.1961.1962.1963.1964.1965.1965: I.IL III.IV..: I ...II...III..9.89.69.910.411.512.211.412.212.312.812.113.112.88.78.98.89.010.010.79.510.411.611.210.011.212.313.413.613.113.413.413.511.514.314.613.612.114.815.35.85.06.26.18.510.910.510.912.09.410.910.47.77.29.37.711.712.79.510.815.315.011.013.814.68.57.98.18.19.39.48.39.49.110.710.211.310.010.68.510.39.212.614.213.812.415.614.715.015.616.412.211.812.412.914.415.314.516.415.015.115.216.614.710.110.310.111.311.411.811.611.811.512.512.212.212.19.19.39.69.210.611.710.211.711.113.711.013.311.96.34.46.96.910.511.610.910.511.213.813.212.712.6Pr<strong>of</strong>its after taxes per dollar <strong>of</strong> sales—cents1947.1948.1949.6.76.85.44.23.33.34.15.25.18.28.34.14.63.12.110.78.56.56.15.24.58.88.88.24.44.73.84.33.32.21950.1951.1952.1953.1954.1955.1956.1957-1958.1959.6.54.54.14.34.45.15.34.94.44.93.42.01.92.02.12.32.42.22.22.44.93.83.23.74.24.85.05.25.45.45.83.41.92.21.02.62.61.91.63.02.8.61.01.21.11.31.61.31.01.58.86.65.75.45.66.16.15.04.75.24.53.73.33.43.43.64.23.73.14.010.36.56.16.16.88.38.07.67.07.911.110.110.410.611.111.610.69.59.55.84.53.63.84.04.44.44.23.54.03.7.61.81.81.92.52.12.01.72.21960.1961.1962.1963.1964.1965.1965: I....II...III.IV..1966: I....II—III.4.84.74.74.95.45.55.45.55.65.65.55.75.62.32.32.32.42.72.72.52.73.02.82.62.82.95.55.75.75.95.95.95.56.06.15.95.46.26.32.52.12.42.33.13.83.73.83.84.13.43.93.71.41.31.61.42.12.31.92.02.72.52.12.52.55.04.74.64.55.14.94.55.04.85.45.35.65.03.62.83.43.24.34.84.94.35.34.75.15.15.57.57.37.47.57.97.97.78.27.97.98.08.27.69.910.39.710.810.911.110.911.010.911.411.111.011.23.63.83.73.64.14.33.94.14.14.94.04.64.41.61.11.81.82.62.82.72.72.73.13.13.03.01 Includes certain industries not shown separately.2 Annual ratios based on average equity for <strong>the</strong> year (using four end-<strong>of</strong>-quarter figures). Quarterlyratios based on equity at end <strong>of</strong> quarter only.NOTE.—Ratios based on data in millions <strong>of</strong> dollars.For explanatory notes concerning compilation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> series, see Quarterly Financial <strong>Report</strong> for ManufacturingCorporations, Federal Trade Commission and Securities and Exchange Commission. See also Note,Table B-67.Data for Alaska and Hawaii included for all periods.Sources: Federal Trade Commission and Securities and Exchange Commission.


TABLE B-69.—Sources and uses <strong>of</strong> funds, nonfarm nonfinancial corporate business, 1955-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Source or use <strong>of</strong> funds 195519561957195819591960196119621963196419651966Sources, totalInternal sources *Undistributed pr<strong>of</strong>its iCorporate inventoryvaluation adjustmentCapital consumptionallowances 1External sourcesStocksBondsMortgagesBank loans, n.e.cO<strong>the</strong>r loansTrade debtPr<strong>of</strong>its tax liability...O<strong>the</strong>r liabilitiesUses, totalPurchases <strong>of</strong> physicalassetsNonresidential fixedinvestmentResidential structuresChange in businessinventoriesIncrease in financial assets2Liquid assetsDemand depositsand currency.-.Time depositsU.S. Governmentsecurities __.Finance companypaperC onsumer creditTrade creditO<strong>the</strong>r financial assets.Discrepancysources)(uses less53.629.213.9-1.717.024.51.92.8.73.2•8.74.13.051.431.525.8.84.919.95.21.0-.14.2 -4.5.1.711.42.3-2.247.228.913.2-2.718.418.32.33.6.44.4*5.7-2.03.943.135.930.7.44.97.2-4.2.1*.1.47.53.4-4.142.030.611.8-1.520.311.42.46.3.41.1.7.5-2.12.240.034.733.4.7.6 -2.55.3-.1**-.4.3.22.62.5-2.042.229.58.3-.321.412.72.15.71.2-.6.24.3-2.62.442.127.328.41.414.82.51.5.9*.1.57.93.5-.155.535.012.6-.522.920.52.23.01.23.0.34.92.43.654.336.931.11.74.117.45.6-1.0-.46.6 -5.4.4.87.23.3-1.147.334.410.0.224.212.91.63.5.71.31.03.1-2.24.045.339.234.91.33.06.1-3.9-.51.3.7.26.33.7-2.054.735.610.2-.125.419.12.54.61.8.1.36.61.21.955.037.033.22.21.518.03.51.71.9-.2.1.110.04.663.341.812.4.329.221.5,64.62.92.5.74.51.14.761.644.737.03.04.716.94.1-.93.7.5.9.98.24.1.3 -1.665.943.913.6-.530.822.0-.33.93.52.9.56.01.54.065.846.738.63.74.319.14.3-.83.9.7.78.54.8-.170.550.818.5-.432.819.71.44.03.33.61.33.4.91.867.152.244.13.74.414.9.7-2.53.21.51.09.14.0-3.388.055.321.7-1.535.132.7*5.43.28.71.37.92.04.287.361.951.33.96.825.4.6-1.93.9.5 -1.4 -2.1.71.213.79.3-.794.058.623.0-2.037.635.4.810.12.26.22.27.8-.36.492.073.859,93.011.018.2-2.51 The figures shown here for "internal sources," "undistributed pr<strong>of</strong>its," and "capital consumptionallowances" differ from those shown for "cash flow,net <strong>of</strong> dividends," "undistributed pr<strong>of</strong>its" and "capitalconsumption allowances" in <strong>the</strong> gross corporate product table in <strong>the</strong> national income and productaccounts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce for <strong>the</strong> following reasons: (1) <strong>the</strong>se figures include, and <strong>the</strong>statistics in <strong>the</strong> gross corporate product table exclude, branch pr<strong>of</strong>its remitted from foreigners net <strong>of</strong> correspondingU.S. remittances to foreigners; and (2) <strong>the</strong>se figuresexclude, and <strong>the</strong> gross corporate productfigures include, <strong>the</strong> internal funds <strong>of</strong> corporations whose major activity is farming.2 Includes some categories not shown separately.NOTE.—Includes data for Alaska and Hawaii.Source: Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System.-2.0-.7-1.92.11.213.26.3-2.0294


TABLE B-70.—Current assets and liabilities <strong>of</strong> United States corporations, 1939-66[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Current assetsCurrent liabilitiesEnd <strong>of</strong> yearor quarterTotalCashonhandandinbanksU.S.GovernmentsecuritiesReceivablesfromU.S.Government1O<strong>the</strong>rnotesandaccountsreceivableInventoriesO<strong>the</strong>rcurrentassets2TotalAdvancesandprepay-ments,U.S.Government1O<strong>the</strong>rnotesandaccountspayableFederalincometaxliabilitiesNetO<strong>the</strong>r workcur-ingrent capilia-bili-tiestal1939194019411942164319441945194619471948194954.560.372.983.693.897.297.4108.1123.6133.0133.110.813.113.917.621.621.621.722.825.025.326.52.22.04.010.116.420.921.115.314.114.816.80.1.64.05.04.72.7.738.342.443.022.123.927.423.321.921.823.230.018.019.825.627.327.626.826.337.644.648.945.31.41.51.41.31.31.42.41.71.61.61.430.032.840.747.351.651.745.851.961.564.460.70.6.82.02.21.837.639.337.521.922.625.624.024.125.024.831.51.22.57.112.616.615.510.48.510.711.59.37.17.28.78.79.49.711.813.213.514.024.527.532.336.342.145.651.656.262.168.672.41950 161.51951 179.11952.21953 . 190.61954 194.628.130.030.831.133.419.720.719.921.519.21.12.72.82.62.455.758.864.665.971.255.164.965.867.265.31.72.12.42.43.179.892.696.198.999.7.41.32.32.22.447.953.657.057.359.316.721.318.118.715.514.916.518.720.722.581.686.590.191.894.91955195619571958195919601961New series 319611962196319641965224.0237.9244.7255.3277.3289.0306.8304.6326.5351.7372.6407.934.634.834.937.436.337.241.140.743.746.547.149.223.519.118.618.822.820.120.019.219.620.218.816.72.32.62.82.82.93.13.43.43.73.63.43.995.199.4106.9117.7126.1135.8133.3144.2156.8170.6189.672.880.482.281.988.491.895.295.2100.7107.0114.0126.34.25.96.77.59.110.611.412.914.717.818.822.1121.0130.5133.1136.6153.1160.4171.2155.8170.9188.2200.3224.52.32.42.31.71.71.81.81.82.02.52.73.173.881.584.388.799.3105.0112.8110.0119.1130.4139.6157.219.317.615.412.915.013.514.114.215.216.517.219.225.729.031.133.337.040.142.529.834.538.740.745.0103.0107.4111.6118.7124.2128.6135.6148.8155.6163.5172.3183.41964: I IIIIIIV.1965: I IIIllIV352. 2358. 6366.2372.6378.4386.3395.4407.942.744.545.147.144.445.845.649.220.819.818.818.818.316.115.816.73.33.03.23.43.33.23.63.9158.5162.9168.8170.6174.6179.9185.2189.6108.3109.3110.9114.0117.1119.4123.1126.318.719.119.518.820.621.922.122.1186.3190.1195.1200.3203.2208.6214.6224.52.62.62.72.72.82.93.13.1128.4131.3134.5139.6141.1145.8150.0157.215.915.516.317.216.816.217.219.239.440.841.740.742.543.844.345.0165.9168.4171.1172.3175.1177.7180.7183.41966: I....II...Ill413.7423.6431.446.947.746.916.915.314.63.94.04.2192.5198.4202.8130.2134.4139.423.423.723.5227.7233.1239.93.83.94.4157.5163.4167.119.116.717.947.349.150.4186.0190.4191.51 Receivables from and payables to U.S. Government do not include amounts <strong>of</strong>fset against each o<strong>the</strong>ron corporations' books or amounts arising from subcontracting which are not directly due from or to <strong>the</strong>U.S. Government. Wherever possible, adjustments have been made to include U.S. Government advances<strong>of</strong>fset against inventories on corporations' books.2 Includes marketable securities o<strong>the</strong>r than U.S. Government.3 Generally reflects definitions and classifications used in Statistics <strong>of</strong> Income for 1961.NOTE.—Data relate to all United States corporations, excluding banks, savings and loan associations,insurance companies, and beginning with <strong>the</strong> new series for 1961, investment companies. Year-end datathrough 1963 are based on Statistics <strong>of</strong> Income (Treasury Department), covering virtually all corporationsin <strong>the</strong> United States. Statistics <strong>of</strong> Income data may not be strictly comparable from year to year because<strong>of</strong> changes in <strong>the</strong> tax laws, basis for filing returns, and processing <strong>of</strong> data for compilation purposes. Allo<strong>the</strong>r figures shown are estimates based on data compiled from many different sources, including data oncorporations registered with <strong>the</strong> Securities and Exchange Commission.Source: Securities and Exchange Commission.295


TABLE B-71.—State and municipal and corporate securities <strong>of</strong>fered, 1934-66 l[Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year or quarterStateandmunicipalsecurities<strong>of</strong>feredfor cash(principalamounts)TotalGross proceeds sComm<strong>of</strong>erredPre-stock stockCorporate securities <strong>of</strong>fered for cash 2BondsandnotesTotalProposed uses <strong>of</strong> net proceeds *TotalNew moneyPlantandequipmentWorkingcapitalRetirement<strong>of</strong> securitiesO<strong>the</strong>rpurposes193419351936193719381939194019411942194319441945194619471948194919501951195219531954195519561957195819591960196119621963196419651966 '1964: I....II...III..IV..1965: I....II...III.IV..1966: I....II-III.IV*9391,2321,1219081,1081,1281,2389565244356617951,1572,3242,6902,9073,5323,1894,4015,5585,9775,4466,9587,4497,6817,2308,3608,55810,10710,54411,14811,0732,6612,7642,6422,4782,7462,9912,7582,6532,8703,1772,4342,5933974,5722,3102,1552,1642,6772,6671,0621,1703,2026,0116,9006,5777,0786,0526,3617,7419,5348,8989,51610,24010,93912,88411,5589,74810,15413,16510,70512,23713,95715,99218,4182,5484,9652,8763,5683,0075,0433,9124,0305,0945,1154,1974,0121922272285258710811034563978917796147368111,2121,2132,1852,3012,5161,3342,0271,6643,2941,3141,0222,6791,5471,9402621,7353573242976652313535199751712753722,2244,0281,6182,0441,9802,3862,3909179902,6704,8554,8825,0365,9734,8904,9205,6917,6017,0837,4887,4208,0029,9579,6537,1908,0819,42010,87210,86513,72015,9082,2483,0762,3823,1602,5784,1233,5293,4904,3594,025962714061831671121247581,1277624924256318385644898166356364115715314094504223424127255701541371322551511872151151433,6413842,2664,4312,2392,1102,1152,6152,6231,0431,1473,1425,9026,7576,4666,9595,9596,2617,6079,3808,7559,36510,04910,74912,66111,3729,5279,92412,88510,50112,08113,79215,80118,1692,5184,9112,8373,5262,9724,9773,8695,0365,0464,1433,944572088589916813254743086571,0803,2794,5915,9294,6064,0066,5318,1807,9606,7807,95711,7849,9078,5788,75810,7158,2408,99311,23313,06316,1932,0864,4412,0772,6292,4274,1643,1773,2964,3204,6443,663321113805745041704246612871412526382,1153,4094,2213,7242,9665,1106,3125,6475,1105,3336,7099,0407,7926,0845,6627,4135,6525,4057,0037,71212,7151,1493,2301,2191,4051,5202,3242,1041,7633,2583,6682,9072,88226478417177155145207187167405442164182708,041,421_,8682,3131,6702,6242,9542,7442,1152,4943,0972,5883,5884,2305,3523,4779371,2118581,2249071,8401,0731,5331,0629767562311,865,100.206,854,5832,3894,5552.8681,3523074011,2714866642601,8751,2273642145491352718687541,52875424110317321626223418833623751725295193204148222951921721731002676105247229529845895375357098647216639158143025075618057417373302975446353116253564496653314283131 These data cover substantially all new issues <strong>of</strong> State, municipal, and corporate securities <strong>of</strong>fered forcash sale in <strong>the</strong> United States in amounts over $100,000 and with terms to maturity <strong>of</strong> more than 1 year.* Excludes notes issued exclusively to commercial banks, intercorporate transactions, sales <strong>of</strong> investmentcompany issues, and issues to be sold over an extended period, such as <strong>of</strong>ferings under employee-purchaseplans.> Number <strong>of</strong> units multiplied by <strong>of</strong>fering price.* Net proceeds represents <strong>the</strong> amount received by <strong>the</strong> issuer after payment <strong>of</strong> compensation to distributorsand o<strong>the</strong>r costs <strong>of</strong> flotation.NOTE.—Data for Alaska and Hawaii included for all periods.Sources: Securities and Exchange Commission, The Commercial and Financial Chronicle, and The BondBuyer.296


TABLE B-72.—Common stock prices, earnings, and yields, and stock market credit, 1939-66Year or month19391940194119421943194419451946194719481949195019511952195319541955195619571958195919601961196219631964196519661965: Jan...Feb..Mar..Apr...May_.June-July..Aug..Sept..Oct...Nov...Dec...1966: Jan...Feb...Mar...Apr...May...June..July..Aug..Sept..Oct...Nov..Dec.Total(500stocks)12.0611.029.828.6711.5012.4715.1617.0815.1715.5315.2318.4022.3424.5024.7329.6940.4946.6244.3846.2457.3855.8566.2762.3869.8781.3788.1785.2686.1286.7587.9789.2885.0484.9186.4989.3891.3992.1591.7393.3292.6988.8891.6086.7886.0685.8480.6577.8177.1380.9981.33Standard & Poor's common stock dataPrice index *Industrials(425stocks)Publicutilities(50stocks)Railroads(25stocks)Dividendyield *(percent)Price/earningsratio 3Stock market creditCustomer credit (excludingTotalU.S. Governmentsecurities)Netdebitances 4Bankloansto'o<strong>the</strong>rs" «1941-43=10 Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars11.7710.699.728.7811.4912.3414.7216.4814.8515.3415.0018.3322.6824.7824.8430.2542.4049.8047.6349.3661.4559.4369.9965.5473.3986.1993.4891.0991.0491.6491.7593.0894.6990.1989.9291.6894.9397.2098.0297.6699.5699.1195.0498.1792.8592.1491.9586.4083.1182.0186.1086.5016.3415.0510.937.7411.3412.8116.8420.7618.0116.7717.8719.9620.5922.8624.0327.5731.3732.2532.1937.2244.1546.8660.2059.1664.9969.9176.0868.2175.8777.0476.9277.2477.5074.1974.6374.7176.1076.6976.7275.3974.5071.8769.2170.0668.4967.5167.3063.4163.1165.4168.8268.869.829.419.398.8111.8113.4718.2119.0914.0215.2712.8315.5319.9122.4922.6023.9632.9433.6528.1127.0535.0930.3132.8330.5637.5845.4646.7846.3446.7946.7646.9846.6345.5342.5243.3146.1346.9648.4650.2351.0353.6854.7851.5252.3347.0046.3545.5042.1240.3139.4441.5741.444.055.596.827.244.934.864.173.854.935.546.596.576.135.805.804.954.084.094.353.973.233.472.983.373.173.013.003.402.992.992.992.952.923.073.093.062.982.912.963.053.023.063.233.153.303.363.373.603.753.763.663.5913.8010.248.268.8012.8413.6616.3317.699.366.906.646.639.2710.479.6911.2511.5014.0512.8916.6417.0517.0921.0616.6817.6218.0817.0817.6915.9317.1017.6116.3114.7113.921,3749761,0329681,2491,7981,8261,9802,4453,4364,0303,9843,5764,5374,4614,4155,6025,4947,2427,0537,7057,4436,9406,8726,9417,0017,0857,0846,8336,8747,0367,1177,3047,7057,7267,9507,8237,9917,9058,0017,8707,8117,5257,3027,3527,4439424735174998211,2371,2531,3321,6652,3882,7912,8232,4823,2853,2803,2224,2594,1255,5155,0795,5215,3294,9865,0075,0555,0665,1295,1144,8864,9945,0735,2095,5215,5515,7535,6455,8355,7685,7705,6675,6095,3555,1695,2175,3293534325035154694285615736487801,0481,239,161,094,252,181,193,343,369,7271,9742,184V14[,954,865,886,935,956,970,970Bankloans tobrokersanddealers 62,0422,0442,0952,1842,1752,1972,1782,1562,1372,231New series 72,2032,2022,1702,1332,1352,1147155845358501,3282,1372,7821,4717841,3311,6081,7421,4192,0022,2482,6882,8522,2142,1902,5692,5842,6143,3984,3524,7544,6314,1354,5014,0113,8514,4344,5714,4955,3253,6733,7103,3233,4803,7344,1353,9853,5073,7524,4184,2604,6543,6874,1793,5453,2683,1074,5011 Annual data are averages <strong>of</strong> monthly figuresand monthly data are averages <strong>of</strong> daily figures.2 Aggregate cash dividends (based on latest known annual rate) divided by <strong>the</strong> aggregate monthly marketvalue <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> stocks in <strong>the</strong> group. Annual yields are averages <strong>of</strong> monthly data.* Ratio <strong>of</strong> quarterly earnings (seasonally adjusted annual rate) to price index for last day in quarter.Annual ratios are averages <strong>of</strong> quarterly data.4 As reported by member firms<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> New York Stock Exchange carrying margin accounts. Includesnet debit balances <strong>of</strong> all customers (o<strong>the</strong>r than general partners in <strong>the</strong> reporting firmand member firms<strong>of</strong>national exchanges) whose combined accounts net to a debit. Balances secured by U.S. Governmentobligations are excluded. Data are for end <strong>of</strong> period." Loans by weekly reporting member banks (weekly reporting large commercial banks beginning July1966) to o<strong>the</strong>rs than brokers and dealers for purchasing or carrying securities except U.S. Government obligations.(For 1953 through June 1959 some loans for purchasing or carrying U.S. Government securitiesmay be included.) Data are for last Wednesday <strong>of</strong> period.6 Loans by weekly reporting member banks (weekly reporting large commercial banks beginning July1966) for purchasing or carrying securities, including U.S. Government obligations. Data are for lastWednesday <strong>of</strong> period.7 See Federal Reserve Bulletin, August 1966.Sources: Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System, Standard & Poor's Corporation, and NewYork Stock Exchange.297


Year or month19291930193119321933193419351936193719381939194019411942194319441945 - - -194619471948194919501951195219531954195519561957195819591960196119621963 *1964196519661965* JanFebMarAprMayJuneJulyAugSeptOctNovDec1966* JanFebMarAprMayJuneJulvAugSeptOctNovDecTABLE B-73.—Business formation and business failures, 1929-66Business failures 3 4Index <strong>of</strong>net businessformation(1957-59=100) i123.196.7102.3102 8108.0103.599 8107.6103.298.397.1104.699.895.498.0100.6104.5106 0105.8106.6106 6106.1104 7105 4106.2106 5105.7lO6 1105.5106 1106.9109.1109 6109 6107 6106 8106.2IO4.810S.9102.7103. S100 6Newbusinessincorporations(number)a132,916112,63896,10185,49192,92583,64992,819102,545117,164139,651140,775136,6977150,280193,067182,713181,535182,057186,404197,724203,89717,27517, S6717,11216,60416 04316,67116,36916,96717,13816,74417,41816,99917,67717,86817,30517,02216,60S16,64116,68816,22415,66416,30516,096Businessfailurerates103.9121.6133.4154.1• 100.361.161.747.845.961.10 69.663.054.544.616.46.54.25.214.320.434.434.330.728.733.242.041.648.051.755.951.857.064.460.856.353.253.351.652.861.754.850.854.150.152.866.969.751.561.454.250.744.150.247.445.849.462.360.856.667.265.652.4Number <strong>of</strong> failuresTotal22,90926,35528,28531,822«19,85912,09112,2449,6079,49012,836•14,76813,61911,8489,4053,2211,2228091,1293,4745,2509,2469,1628,0587,6118,86211,08610,96912,68613,73914,96414,05315,44517,07515,78214,37413,50113,51413,0611,1371 1141,3321,1791 1831,0941 0741,1311,1001,0471,0331,0901,0849461 2261 1069971,0771 0171,2491,0401,1501,1121,055Liability sizeclassUnder$100,000$100,000andover22,16525,40827,23030,197•18,88011,42111,6919,2859,20312 553• 14,54113,40011,6859,2823,1551,1767591,0023,1034,8538,7088,7467,6267,0818,07510,22610,11311,61512,54713,49912,70713,65015,00613,77212,19211,34611,34010,8339509301,0971,0301 0018819069658939128938829168001 0379248478858799998679579198037449471,0551,625• 979670553322287283• 2272191631236646501273713975384164325307878608561,0711,1921,4651,3461,7952,0692,0102,1822,1552,1742,228187184235149182213168166207135140208168146189182150192138250175193193252Amount <strong>of</strong> currentliabilities (millions <strong>of</strong>dollars)Total483.3668.3736 3928 3«457.5334 0310 6203 2183 3246 5• 182.5166 7136 1100 845 331.730.267.3204.6234 6308.1248.3259.5283.3394.2462 6449.4562.7615.3728.3692.8938.61,090.11,213.61,352.61,329.21 321.71,385.789.3112.0146.683.2133.1144.6121.5135.0105.082.171.797.6103.295.5103.5110.196.4123.669.9178.1129.2108.0106.7161.5Liability sizeclassUnder $100,000$100,000 andover261.5303.5354.2432.6• 215.5138.5135.5102.8101.9140.1«132.9119.9100.780.330.214.511.415.763.793.9161.4151.2131.6131.9167.5211.4206.4239.8267.1297.6278.9327.2370.1346.5321.0313.6321.7321.526.725.631.128.928.225.025.828.025.524.925.526.327.124.228.626.123.926.526.230.725.429.629.024.2221.8364.8382.2495.7• 242.0195.4175.1100.481.4106.48 49.746.835.420.515.117.118.851.6140.9140.7146.797.1128.0151.4226.6251.2243.0322.9348.2430.7413.6611.4720.0867.11,031.61,015.61,000.01, 064.162.586.3115.454.3104.9119.695.7107.079.457.246.271.376.071.374.884.172.597.143.6147.4103.878.477.8137.21 Monthly data are seasonally adjusted.2 Total for period. Monthly data are seasonally adjusted.3 Total for period.« Commercial and industrial failures only. Excludes failures <strong>of</strong> banks and railroads and, beginning 1933,<strong>of</strong> real estate, insurance, holding, and financial companies, steamship lines, travel agencies, etc.* Failure rate per 10,000 listed enterprises. Monthly data are seasonally adjusted.« Series revised; not strictly comparable with earlier data.7 Includes data for Hawaii beginning 1959 and Alaska beginning 1960. (Figure for 1958 comparable with1959 is 150,781; figure for 1960 comparable with 1959 is 182,374.)8 Includes data for District <strong>of</strong> Columbia beginning 1963.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce (Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Census) and Dun & Bradstreet, Inc.298


AGRICULTURETABLE B-74.—Income from agriculture, 1929-66Year orquarterPersonal incomereceived by totalfarm populationFromallsourcesFromfarmsourcesFromnonfarmsources iRealized grossTotal 2Income received from farmingNet to farmoperatorsCashreceiptsfrommarketingsProductionexpensesExcludingnetinventorychangeIncludingnetinventorychange 3Net income perfarm, includingnet inventorychangeCurrentprices1966prices *Billions <strong>of</strong> dollarsDollars192913.911.37.76.36.2945J Q9Q1930193119321933 _19341935193619371938 ---19395.47.77.29.07.27.43.25.44.66.24.74.82.22.32.62.72.52.611.58.46.47.18.69.710.811.410.110.69.16.44.75.36.47.18.48.97.77.96.95.54.54.44.75.15.66.25.96.34.52.91.92.73.94.65.15.24.24.34.33.32.02.62.95.34.36.04.44.46515063043794317756399056686851,4151,297894L, 1151,1051,987.fi382,2071,7131,803194019411942. .19431944194519461947194819497.610.114.116.516.617.220.021.123.819.54.86.810.112.112.212.815.515.818.013.32.83.33.94.44.44.44.65.35.86.211.113.918.823.424.425.829.534.134.731.68.411.115.619.620.521.724.829.630.227.86.97.810.011.612.313.114.517.018.818.04.26.18.811.812.112.815.017.115.913.64.56.59.911.711.712.315.115.417.712.87061,0311,5881,9271,9502,0632,5432,6153,0442,2331,8582,5153,3793,6363,4823,5573,9733,4873,8052,900195019511952 .19531954195519561957 .1958195920.422.722.119.818.417.617.817.719.518.114.116.215.413.412.511.411.211.012.811.06.36.56.76.45.96.26.66.66.77.032.337.136.835.033.633.134.334.037.937.528.532.932.531.029.829.530.429.733.533.519.422.322.621.321.621.922.423.325.226.112.914.814.113.712.011.211.910.712.711.413.716.015.113.112.511.511.411.313.511.52,4212,9462,8962,6262,6062,4632,5352,5903,1892,7953,1043,4663,3673,0893,0302,8642,9142,8783,5043,0711960196119621963 _ -196419651966 P18.719.019.218.717.920.621.311.412.112.212.011.113.714.57.26.97.06.76.76.86.837.939.641.142.142.344.949.534.034.936.237.236.939.242.926.227.028.529.629.430.733.211.712.612.512.512.914.216.312.012.913.113.112.115.216.13,0433,3893,5623,6713,4794,4934,9553,3083,6843,7893,8643,6624,6324,955Seasonally adjusted annual rates1965: IIIIIIIV42.945.445.545.937.339.739.740.030.030.830.931.212.914.614.614.712.915.516.116.13,8204,5904,7704,7703,9804,7304,9204,9201966: IIIIII.IV P48.448.749.851.142.242.243.044.131.932.533.834.616.516.216.016.517.116.415.515.35,2605,0404,7704,7105,3105,0404,7204,6601 Includes all income received by farm residents from nonfarm sources such as wages and salaries fromnonfarm employment, nonfarm business and pr<strong>of</strong>essional income, rents from nonfarm real estate, dividends,interest, royalties, unemployment compensation, and social security payments.2 Cash receipts from marketings, Government payments, and nonmoney income furnished by farms.* Includes net change in inventory <strong>of</strong> crops and livestock valued at <strong>the</strong> average price for <strong>the</strong> year.* Income in current prices divided by <strong>the</strong> index <strong>of</strong> prices paid by farmers for family living items on a1966 base.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture.299


Year1929...1930...1931...1932...1933...1934...1935...1936...1937...1938...1939...1940...1941..-1942..-1943...1944...1945...1946...1947...1948.--1949...1950.-1951...1952.-1953.-1954.-1955.-1956...1957...1958...1959.-1960.-1961.-1962.-1963_-1964.-1965..-1966 »..Farmoutputi6261666459516155696768707382808381848188878689929393969795102103106107108112112115113TABLE B-75.—Farm production indexes, 1929-66Total 2FeedHavgrainsandFood Vegetablesforagegrains7369777365547059817675787989838885898597928991959493969593104103108107107112109116112625663735633603867656566718174787582639180817579778186859310110610999100110971111117966727469648266758175868693919093878484838992909292989410110297103102105105105112110687479634745555474776369798372889295111107928685109100888387821219711510698102114116118[1957-59*100]Crops737475767380817582818183848997929410591979496899095939610298102100103110108108103109110Fruitsandnuts757392757671907093849693999884988910610192989810097989999103941021049810998102111118122CottonTobaccocropsOil TotaP78 107 165 111120113138105105788610115497961028810593100747197122131821241241341111201088993118116116121125124121889589588063766891801108473818111311413412211511411713513011913012712696100104112119134135129107131414131113211618222934375660505452556761716563637178929111198105122123128128154636465666761596362657071758491868683828085889292939699999799104102106107111113111Livestock and productsMeatanimals6263666770595360586371727687978884828179838995959498103100969810610310610811411611011175767879797878797981828489929192959493909393929297989910110110099101103104103105104101DairyproductsPoultryandeggs* Farm output measures <strong>the</strong> annual volume <strong>of</strong> farm production available for eventual human use throughsales from farms or consumption in farm households. Total excludes production <strong>of</strong> feed for horses andmules.* Includes production <strong>of</strong> feed forhorses and mules and certain items not shown separately.8 Includes certain items not shown separately.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture.4445444444414144444548495462717174696867747881828487869495101104104112111115118122128300


TABLE B-76.—Farm population, employment, and productivity, 1929-66YearFarm population(April 1) iNumber(thousands)As percent<strong>of</strong>totalpopulation2Farm employment(thousands) 3TotalFamily Hiredworkers workersPerunit<strong>of</strong>totalinputFarm outputTotalPer man-hourCropsLivestockCropproductionperacre 4LivestockproductionperbreedingunitIndex, 1957-59=1001929.1931.1932.1933.1934.1935.1936.1937.1938.1940.1941.1942.1943.1944.1945.1946.1947.1948.1949.30,58030,52930,84531,38832,39332,30532,16131,73731,26630,98030,84030,54730,11828,91426,18624,81524,42025,40325,82924,38324,19425.224.924.925.225.825.525.324.824.223.823.523.122.621.419.217.917.518.017.916.616.212,76312,49712,74512,81612,73912,62712,73312,33111,97811,62211,33810,97910,66910,50410,44610,21910,00010,29510,3829,9649,3609,3079,6429,9229,8749,7659,8559,3509,0548,8158,6118,3008,0177,9498,0107,9887,8818,1068,1158,0267.7123,4033,1903,1032,8942,8652,8622,8782,9812,9242,8072,7272,6792,6522,5552,4362,2312,1192,1892,2672,3372,25263636969655969627374727275827982828582888628283030282731293335353639424244464950565728273030272731283335343739434144465050575748474747464344464648505051565856585961626669647268615166567673747677867883828682928570706862707175757580817875797879821950.1951.1952.1953.1954.1955..1956.1957.1958.1959.1960.1961.1962.1963.1964.1965...1966*..23,04821,89021,74819,87419,01919,07818,71217,65617,12816,59215,63514,80314,31313,36712,95412,36311,50015.214.213.912.511.711.511.110.39.89.48.78.17.77.16.76.45.89,9269,5469,1498,8648,6518,3797,8537,6007,5037,3427,0576,9196,7006,5186,1105,6105,2597,5977,3107,0056,7756,5706,3455,8995,6605,5215,3905,1725,0294,8734,7384,5064,1283,9022,3292,2362,1442,0892,0812,0341,9541,9401,9821,9521,8851,8901,8271,7801,6041,4821,35785868990919496961031011051061071101091121096162687174808691103106115120127135142153157636167697377839010510511411912413213315014968727476808589921001081131201271371471541618485908988919293105102109113116119116123120898993929395961001041051081081111121101141 Farm population as defined by Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, i.e., civilianpopulation living on farms, regardless <strong>of</strong> occupation.2 Total population <strong>of</strong> United States as <strong>of</strong> July 1 includes armed forces abroad and Alaska and Hawaiibeginning January and August 1959, respectively.* Includes persons doing farm work on all farms. These data, published by <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture,Statistical <strong>Report</strong>ing Service, differ from those on agricultural employment by <strong>the</strong> Department<strong>of</strong> Labor (see Table B-20) because <strong>of</strong> differences in <strong>the</strong> method <strong>of</strong> approach, in concepts <strong>of</strong> employment,and in time <strong>of</strong> month for which <strong>the</strong> data are collected. For fur<strong>the</strong>r explanation, see monthly report onFarm Labor, September 10,1958.* Computed from variable weights for individual crops produced each year.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce (Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Census).240-782 O—67--20301


TABLE B-77.—Indexes <strong>of</strong> prices received and prices paid by farmers, and parity ratio, 1929-66[1957-59=100]Year or month192919301931 _ _19321933193419351936193719381939 .—194019411942194319441945 _1946194719481949 .1950 -195119521953195419551956195719581959I9601961196219631964 _196519661965: Jan 15Feb 15 .-Mar 15Apr 15 .May 15June 15July 15Augl5Sept 15Octl5Novl5Dec 151966' Jan 15Feb 15Mar 15Apr 15May 15June 15July 15Augl5Sept 15Octl5Novl5Dec 15Allfarmprod-61523627293745475140394251668 808 826 868 9811411910310712511910510296959710499999910110098102110989899101104105104103103103103107108112111110109109110113112110107107Prices received by fannersCropsAllrops 1615234263244464953363741486584899110211811410010411912010810810410510110099991021041071071041051051051071091111081041001009993100101104104106107108110108106104103103Foodgrains55442721314346515735344046577078819512811810310611511611111010710610698969699107106907787797978777674767676777980818281798289969493898990 Feed grainsand hayTotal746746313660686579454654587296108106127161162112122143147130128116115105979895959710310510911311011511311210810810198105108110107108110110115118120116115118Feedgrains77684428366070688445445458739710910413117117010912314715013213011611610597989394951011021061111061071081101121131111071069994101105106104106109109114117119114113116Cotton5740241926393838362728324360646669911051049410812911910210510410310197102971001041041009482908993959797979395959490868690929294976969737171 Tobacco3529201822323533413631283251667274787778828390898991909396100104103109109102101106114101103103103103103103107109109113113111112112113113113113115118116111116Oilbearingcrops62483219254555525642424560808897100114158153106120148129122133109111106989693112108113112116128120123123123119120118112107107107111117121119121124128138148133128128129Livestock and productsAlllivestockandproducts16252382827324446494341425366777682941111221061081301191049790889410610098989995911011139293939599103104105105106107112114118118113110110111116116114110109Meatanimals504330201922383842373635466066626 6710711710111013311594928076891091029697101948810411688919295104111111111108108108116120125123119117117114119115111105105Dairyucts65554333344045495145434755636776 866 104106117989711211810496969910199100101101999910010211410410210097949497101105108110110108108108106104104111117124128127125Poultryandeggs102816251475674737069616277961211121261271411531401181441301401131211121021089010192929290921028787889187889093959698104101108110102959397103106101103100See footnotes at end <strong>of</strong> table.302


TABLE B-77.—Indexes <strong>of</strong> prices received and prices paid by farmers, and parity ratio, 1929-66—Continued[1957-59=100]Prices paid by fannersYear or month19291930..-.1931.....19321933..—1934.....1935193619371938.—.1939.....194019411942.....194319441945....1946....1947....1948....1949....1950....1951195219531954..-1955...-1957..1958..1959..I960..1961..1962.196419651966 * -1965: Jan 15..—Febl5....Mar 15....Apr 15....May 15...June 15..July 15...Augl5._.Sept 15—Octl5.__Nov 15...Dec 15...1966: Jan 15.....Feb 15...Mar 15...Apr 15—May 15...June 15..July 15...Augl5...Sept 15...Octl5...Nov 15...Dec 15...Allitems,interest,taxes,andwagerates(parityindex)555244383741424245424242455258626571828986879595949598100102102103105107107110114108109109109110110110110110110110HI112112113114114114114114115115115115AllItems4345454845444548556164667285928890100100969695101101101101103104104106109104105105106107107107106106106106107108108109109109109109110111110110110livingItems5450433738434343454342424552586164718388858694959494959699100101102102103104105107110106106106106108107107107107107107108108109110110110110110111111111111111Commodities and servicesFamilyAllproductionitems565243383844464650474647505763666773859591941041049797969598100102101101103104103105108104104104105106106106106106105105106107108108108108108109109110109109109Production itemsFeed Motorvehicles61433237525355624747505466788786100118125103105118126114113106103101991001001041031041091041041041051051051041041041031021031051071051051061061101111131121111133535343436373839424040424547515355637178788387878996100104102102105109111113118113115114110111113115117116118117119118434342403940414243444343434648494951586776788386878787929610010410711011111311611912411811912112112212412685941001021031021011001001001001001001001009910010010010010010010010010010011611310810190807468646058565451464341404243454954596368748391100109120131145162182206232204204204204204204204204204204204206232232232232232232232232232232232232Taxes*Wagerates*5657565144383636363837373739434856606568717477818793100107117125132139147156165155155155155155155155155155155155156165165165165165165165165165165165165929699105109110114116119125135122122122126ite1261251251251281281281271271271S81S81S81S51S51S5HO140HOFarmmachineryFertilizerInterest^Parityratio»9283675864758892937877819310511310810911311511010010110710092898483828581807980787677807475757678797877777777808083818079798081807977771 Includes items not shown separately.2 Interest payable per acre on form real estate debt.3 Farm real estate taxes payable per acre (levied in preceding year).4 Monthly data are seasonally adjusted.5 Percentage ratio <strong>of</strong> prices received for all farm products to parity index, on a 1910-14=100 base.6 Includes wartime subsidy payments.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture.303


TABLE B—78.—Selected measures <strong>of</strong> farm resources and inputs, 1929-66192919301931193219331934Year193519361937.1938193919401941 ,1942194319441945194619471948194919501951195219531954195519561957195819591960196119621963196419651966*Cropsharvested(millions<strong>of</strong> acres) 1Total365369365371340304345323347349331341344348357354352355356360345344349348346340324324324324324303295300301299296Exclusive<strong>of</strong>use forfeed forhorsesandmules298304303311281247269295301286298304309320326322323329332326326334335335330315316317318319299291296297292LivestochoursMan-breeding<strong>of</strong>farmunitswork(1957-(billions)59=100) 223.222.923.495 22.622.620.221.120.422.120.620.795 20.594 20.0104 20.6117 20.3114 20.2109 18.8107 18.1104 17.298 16.816.2102 15.1103 15.2103 14.5100 14.0104 13.3106 12.8104 12.0101 11.199 10.5100 10.397 9.89.59.1100 8.8101 8.4101 8.097 7.6Total98979693918688"8994919497971001011019999991001011011041031031021021019999102101101101102103103104Index numbers <strong>of</strong> inputs (1957-59=100)Farmlabor218216220213212190198192208193194192188194191190177170162158152142143136131125120113104999792898583797572MechanicalFarmreal powerestate 3 andmachinery92 3891 4089 3886 3587 3286 3288 3389 3590 3891 4092 4092 4292 4491 4889 5088 5188 5491 5892 6495 7295 8097 8698 9299 9699 97100 98100 9999 99100 100100 99100 101100 100100 97101 97101 99102 10110099101103Fertilizerandlime212116111214172024232428303438434553565761687380838890919497109110116124141155163164Feed,seed,andlivestockpurchases41 Acreage harvested (excluding duplication) plus acreages in fruits, tree nuts, and farm gardens.2 Animal units <strong>of</strong> breeding livestock, excluding horses and mules.3 Includes buildings and improvements on land.* Nonfarm inputs associated with farmers' purchases.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture.2726232424242331293037454657636472697372697280818082869193101106109123121124123124130Miscellaneous76767879766966707273747576767677787482859191949895100105106109113115120124128304


TABLE B-79.—Comparative balance sheet <strong>of</strong> agriculture, 7929-67[Billions <strong>of</strong> dollars]AssetsClaimsO<strong>the</strong>r physical assetsFinancial assetsBeginning<strong>of</strong> yearCrops 2U.S.savingsbondsTotalRealestatedebtO<strong>the</strong>rdebtMa-TotalReal chin-eryestateLivestockiandmotorvehiclesHouseholdfurnishingsandequipmentDepositsandcurrencyInvestmentin cooperativesProprietors'equities19291930193119321933193468.548.047.943.737.230.832.26.66.54.93.63.03.23.23.43.33.02.52.22.54.03.60.668.59.89.69.49.18.57.75.053.91935193619371938193933.334.335.235.234.13.55.25.15.05.12.22.42.63.03.27.67.47.27.06.8194019411942 _194319441945 -19461947...1948194952.955.062.973.784.694.2103.5116.4127.9134.933.634.437.541.648.253.961.068.573.776.65.15.37.19.69.79.09.711.913.314.43.13.34.04.95.46.55.45.37.410.12.73.03.85.16.16.76.37.19.08.64.24.24.95.05.35.66.17.78.59.13.23.54.25.46.67.99.410.29.99.60.2.4.51.12.23.44.24.24.44.6.8.9.91.01.11.21.41.51.71.952.955.062.973.784.694.2103.5116.4127.9134.96.66.56.46.05.44.94.84.95.15.33.43.94.14.03.53.43.23.64.26.142.944.652.463.775.785.995.5107.9118.6123.519501951195219531954 . -132.5151.5167.0164.3161.275.386.695.196.595.012.917.119.514.811.712.214.116.717.418.47.67.98.89.09.28.69.710.39.99.99.19.19.49.49.44.74.74.74.64.72.12.32.52.72.9132.5151.5167.0164.3161.25.66.16.77.27.76.87.08.08.99.2120.1138.4152.3148.2144.3195519561957.1958195919601961..196219631964196519661967 P165.1169.7178.0186.0202.8203.9204.3213.0220.7229.2237.9255.8273.398.2102.9110.4115.9124.4129.9131.4137.4142.8150.7159.4171.1184.211.210.611.013.917.715.615.516.417.215.714.417 518.619.320.220.222.122.322.022.522.724.125.727. R66.59.68.38.37.69.37.88.08.79.29.98.99. fi10.010.510.09.99.89.68.99.19.08.88.78.69.49.59.49.510.09.28.78.89.29.29.610.05.05.25.15.15.24.74.64.54.44.24.24.122.63.13.43.63.94.34.85.25.66.26.67.07.4165.1169.7178.0186.0202.8203.9204.3213.0220.7229.2237.9255.8273 38.29.09.810.411.112.112.813.915.216.818.921.223 59.49.89.610.012.612.813.414.816.618.118.620.422.3147.5150.9158.6165.6179.1179.0178.1184.3188.9194.3200.4214.2227.51 Beginning with 1961, horses and mules are excluded.2 Includes all crops held on farms and crops held <strong>of</strong>f farms by farmers us security for Commodity CreditCorporation loans. The latter on January 1,1966, totaled $570 million.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture.305


INTERNATIONAL STATISTICSTABLE B-80.—United States balance <strong>of</strong> payments, 1947-66[Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year or quarterExports <strong>of</strong> goods and servicesTotalMerchandise!MilitaryIncome oninvestmentsPrivateGovernmentO<strong>the</strong>rImports <strong>of</strong> goods andservicesTotalMerchandise^MilitaryexpendituresO<strong>the</strong>rBalanceongoodsandservicesRemittancesandpensions1947...1948...1949...1950...1951...1952...1953...1954-1955...1956...1957...1958...1959...1960...1961...1962...1963...1964...1965...1966 ».1964: I..II_IIIIV1965: I__IIIIIIV1966: I—II 19,73716,78915,77013,80718,74417,99216,94717,75919,80423,59526,48123,06723,48927,24428,57530,27832,33936,95838,99342,68716,01513,19312,14910,11714,12313,31912,28112,79914,28017,37919,39016,26416,29519,48919,95420,60422,07125,29726,27628,9611822001613753003354026566577478441,0361,238,297,484,684,624,658,9552,1702,4682,6122,5382,6943,0013,5613,9544,1564,9325,683661021091982042522722741942053073493493804714984605122,6202,2562,2262,0972,7392,8452,5642,5512,8803,3933,6583,8494,0704,2784,5934,9575,5225,9726,5528,20810,3499,62112,02815,07315,76616,56115,93117,79519,62820,75220,86123,34223,19822,95425,14826,44228,46832,03637,2005,9797,5636,8799,10811,20210,83810,99010,35411,52712,80413,29112,95215,31014,73214,51016,18716,99218,62121,48825,2334557996215761,2702,0542,6152,6422,9012,9493,2163,4353,1073,0692,9813,0832,9362,8342,8813,5871,7741,9872,1212,3442,6012,8742,9562,9353,3673,8754,2454,4744,9255,3975,4635,8786,5147,0137,6678,38011,5296,4406,1491,7793,6712,2263861,8282,0093,9675,7292,2061474,0465,6215,1305,8978,4906,9575,487-728-631-641-533-480-571-644-597-690-729-745-815-732-757-867-879-1,000Seasonally adjusted annual rates36,44836,00437,23238,14835,10440,54440,06440,26041,98042,28843,79224,62424,36825,55626,64022,50027,19227,30428,10828,68428,44429,7567927446488048009167968647921,0408605,0804,9444,9404,7645,6885,8805,2844,7045,5245,7205,8045285325322485565845963125965965885,4245,4165,5565,6925,5605,9726,0846,2726,3846,4886,78427,40028,12828,78429,56028,65632,34832,98034,16035,70436,84839,04817,55618,31619,00819,60418,62421,92422,38023,02424,01625,04826,6362,9602,9002,7442,7322,6562,8042,9803,0843,4163,5963,7486,8846,9127,0327,2247,3767,6207,6208,0528,2728,2048,6649,0487,8768,4488,5886,4488,1967,0846,1006,2765,4404,744-848-852-896-920-908-1,152-976-940-944-944-1,112See footnotes at end <strong>of</strong> table.306


Year orquarterTABLE B-80.—United States balance <strong>of</strong> payments, 1947-66—ContinuedU.S.Governmentgrantsandnet 2U.S. private capital,netDirectinvestment[Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]O<strong>the</strong>rlongtermShorttermForeigncapital,net 2BalanceErrorsandunrecordedtransactionsLiquiditybasis 3OfficialreservetransactionsChanges in selected liabilities(decrease (-))«To foreign<strong>of</strong>ficial holders 6LiquidNonliquidToo<strong>the</strong>rforeignholderssChangesin gold,convertiblecurrencies,andIMFgoldtrancheposition(increase())1947.19481949.-6,121-4,918-5,649-749-721-49-69-80-116187-432-361449491,1937864,210817136-3,315-1,736-266I960.1951.1952.1953.1954.-3,640-3,191-2,380-2,055-1,554-621-508-852-735-667-495-437-214185-320-149-103-94167-63518154052146249-11 -3,489500 -8627 —1, 206366 -2,184191 -1,5411,758-33-4151,2564801955.1956.1957.1958.1959.-2,211-2,362-2,574-2,587-1,9861,951•2,442:, 181,372-241-1,444-926-191-517-276-311-77297615545186736515 -1,242568 -9731,184 578511 -3,365423 -3,870182-1,1652,2921,0351960_1961.1962.1963.1964.-2,769-2,780-3,013-3,581-3,560,674,599,654,976-2,416-863-1,025-1,227-1,695-1,961-1,348-1,556-544-785-2,1463667071,021689685-941 -3,881-1,006 -2,370-1,159 -2,203-352 -2,670-1,011 -2,798-3,402-1,347-2,706-2,044-1,546ioi,449i»68110 4571,6731,073254-73022136191,5542,1436061,5333781711965_1966-3,375-3,608-3,371-3,151-1,-443761-531942,016-429-461-1,337-1,213-1,305655-171001321,222Seasonally adjusted annual ratesQuarterly totals unadjusted1964: I.II...III-IV..1965: I....II-..III..IV..1966: III..-3,048 -1,916-3,416 -2,144-3,540 -2,488-4,236 -3,116-3,208 -4,848-3,796 -3,436-2,972 -2,276-3,524 -2,924-3,792 -2,748-3,856 -3,904-3,176 -2,800-1.G64-1,120-2,408-3,252-2,656404-1,452-616-876-320-132-2,460 480 1,184 -992-2,276 -608 -2,208-1,460 -812 -2,468-2,388 1,2 -1,440 -5,5241,084 1,300 -2,7881,648 -524 -436 904420 -l,C04 -960 -2,136-108 1,004 -320 -1,3281,156 -1,188 -2,204-152 3,840 -668 -56480 1,052 472 -872-576-1,304-924-3,380-2,472956928-4,632-964-8563,78440021538986986010725369785158614-342322291-23-16-1815725254105227114562651203-150712-633475261,243-5130370-1518426841271424681 Adjusted from customs data for differences in timing and coverage.2 Includes certain special Government transactions.3 Equals changes in liquid liabilities to foreign <strong>of</strong>ficial holders, o<strong>the</strong>r foreign holders, and changes in <strong>of</strong>ficialreserve assets consisting <strong>of</strong> gold, convertible currencies, and <strong>the</strong> U.S. gold tranche position in <strong>the</strong> IMF.4 Equals changes in liquid and nonliquid liabilities to foreign <strong>of</strong>ficial holders and changes in <strong>of</strong>ficial reserveassets consisting <strong>of</strong> gold, convertible currencies, and <strong>the</strong> U.S. gold tranche position in <strong>the</strong> IMF.3 Includes short-term <strong>of</strong>ficial and banking liabilities, foreign holdings <strong>of</strong> U.S. Government bonds and notes,and certain nonliquid liabilities to foreign <strong>of</strong>ficial holders.6 Central banks, governments, and U.S. liabilities to <strong>the</strong> IMF arising from reversible gold sales to, andgold deposits with <strong>the</strong> U.S. Data for years before 1960 include estimates <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial transactions in marketableU.S. Government bonds and notes.7 Provisional.8 Private holders; includes banks and international and regional organizations, excludes IMF.9 Not reported separately.i° Includes change in Treasury liabilities to certain foreign military agencies; excluding <strong>the</strong>se changes,data ($ millions) are 1,259 (1960), 741 (1961), 919 (1962).ii Average for <strong>the</strong> first 3 quarters on a seasonally adjusted annual rates basis.NOTE.—Data exclude military grant-aid and U.S. subscriptions to International Monetary Fund.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s.307


TABLE B—81.—United States merchandise exports and imports, by commodity groups, 1958—66[Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Year or quarter1958-I960..1961-1962..1963..1964-1965-1966'1964: I-..II..III.IV..1965: I-.-II..III-IV..1966: I-...II-..III-IV9.Total,includingreexports *6,1736,1856,tf96,7895,5686,8706,9187,1067,1787,1817,5017,600Merchandise exports *.6,373 16,208.6,406 16,22226,56' 26,22429,500 28,5006,1856,4146,0367,0365,5937,1286,4367,4107,0907,4397,0387,900Seasonallad-Un-adjusteustedTo-19,638 19,43720,188 19,94320,973 20,70422,427 22,14225,67125,3186,1016,3145,9566,9475,5227,0426,3467,3146,9317,0906,7997,700Domestic exportsFood,beverages,andtobacco2,6882,8523,1453,4223,6774,0964,6384,5215,2001,1481,1341,0511,3058461,1631,1771,3351,25'1,2531,3141,400Crudematerialsand'uelsManufactured;oods3,051 11,546 13,1672,996 11,171 15,4163,89812,892 15,0163,817 13,03714,6603,32313,912 16,2444,274 17,258 21,2824,400 19,000 25,5001,0391,0201,0351,2459161,1709861,2021,0231,0901,0301,300Importsforconsumption73,74114,611: 17,002 ,4,33916,36618, i,6003,9354,1583,8874,3863,7664,7174,1074,6684,6504,8924,5354,9004,3494,5584,6735,0204,6185,4195,1586,0875,8326,2296,5556,900Merchandise importsTotal *4,8954,5814,6585,4516,2845,9446,0016,8086,6656,600General imports 3SeasonallyadjustedUnadjusted13,22015,62915,01914,71616,38217,14018,68421,36625,6004,3724,6084,6655,0394,6095,4875,1466,1245,8976,3416,5466,800Food, 3rude Manbeveragesteturedma-ufac-and rials goodsto- andbacco fuels 8 ( 6 )3,5503,5803,3923,4553,6744,0224,0134,6009679829111,1628281,0279121,2461,1121,1651,1121,2004,0624,5804,3804,6404,6934,9641,2091,2291,2791,2471,2921,3891,3001,4041,4101,4381,4561,4005,2837,0906,8466,5237,6278,0669,1085,385 11,2385,70014,4002,0502,2572,3292,4722,3322,8972,7523,2573,1873,5223,7663,900Grossmerchandisetradesurplus,seasonallyadjusted( 8 )3,1537774,6195,4724,5915,2876,9875,2013,9001,7781,6041,7841,8999151,4191,6791,1621,1778788861,0001 Data for 1964 only have been adjusted for comparability with <strong>the</strong> revised commodity classificationseffective in 1965.2 Totals exclude Department <strong>of</strong> Defense shipments <strong>of</strong> grant-aid military supplies and equipment under<strong>the</strong> Military Assistance Program.3 Total arrivals <strong>of</strong> imported goods o<strong>the</strong>r than intransit shipments.4 Total includes commodities and transactions not classified according to kind.5 Includes fats and oils.8 Includes machinery, transportation equipment, chemicals, metals, and o<strong>the</strong>r manufactures. Exportdata for <strong>the</strong>se items include military grant-aid shipments.7 Imported merchandise released from Customs custody for entry into U.S. consumption channels, entriesinto bonded manufacturing warehouses, and imported ores and crude metals which have been processedin bonded smelting warehouses.8 Exports, excluding military grant-aid, less general imports.» Totals based on data for October, November, and estimates for December.NOTE.—Data are as reported by <strong>the</strong> Bureau <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Census. Export statistics cover all merchandiseshipped from <strong>the</strong> U.S. customs area, except supplies for U.S. Armed Forces. Export values are f.a.s. port<strong>of</strong> export and include shipments under Agency for International Development and Food for Peace programsas well as o<strong>the</strong>r private relief shipments. Import statistics are valued f.o.b., <strong>the</strong> foreign port <strong>of</strong> export, andexclude insurance, transportation, and o<strong>the</strong>r charges incident to arrival in <strong>the</strong> United States. Data includetrade <strong>of</strong> Alaska, Hawaii, and Puerto Rico.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Bureau <strong>of</strong> International Commerce.308


TABLE B—82.—United States merchandise exports and imports, by area, 1960-66[Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Area 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965January-November1965 1966Exports (including reexportsand special category shipments):TotalDeveloped countriesDeveloping countriesCanadaO<strong>the</strong>r Western HemisphereWestern EuropeEastern EuropeAsiaAustralia and Oceania.-.AfricaGeneral imports: TotalDeveloped countriesDeveloping countriesCanadaO<strong>the</strong>r Western HemisphereWestern EuropeEastern EuropeAsiaAustralia and Oceania..AfricaUnidentified countries i.20,586 20,998 21,700 23,3472,7212,960 3,192266 320 440 502627 671 754 77819 4 143,964 3,725 3,931 4,0214,188 4,062 4,544 4,73181 81 79 8113,2597,13213,5647,30013,9857,59015,1248,0563,8104,045 4,2513,875 3,849 3,679 3,6927,211 7,237 7,633 8,171195 134 125 1674,187 4,643 4,673 5,448515 450 522 565793 859 1,023 1,05315,0198,9515,9843,15314,7168,9105,7213,27016,38210,2506,04917,14010,8086,2473,82926,489 27,346 24,740 27,6334,150 4,373 3,920 4,3215,208 6,155 5,510 7,00499 138 121 1613,620 4,529 4,082 4,874440 453 416 551916 875 785 90012 11 10 817,1828,9674,91518,1839,0245,64416,4788,1455,11918,2849,1696,0784,292 4,275 3,847 4,3229,076 9,177 8,281 8,996340 139 117 1806,013 5,431 6,091804 869 808 7391,259 1,229 1,137 1,22718,68411,8946,6874,23921,36614,0687,1564,83219,20612,6716,4114,36223,32116,0077,1505,502i Consists <strong>of</strong> certain low-valued shipments and some uranium imports, not identified by country.NOTE.—Developed countries include, Canada, Western Europe, Japan, Australia, New Zealand, and<strong>the</strong> Republic <strong>of</strong> South Africa. Developing countries include rest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> world except Communist areas inEastern Europe (except Yugoslavia) and Asia.Data include trade <strong>of</strong> Alaska, Hawaii and Puerto Rico.Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Bureau <strong>of</strong> International Commerce.309


TABLE B—83.—United States foreign assistance, by type and area, fiscal years 1946-66[Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]Net obligations and loan authorizationsType and fiscal periodTotalNearEastandSouthAsiaLatinAmericaFarEastAfricaEuropeO<strong>the</strong>rand nonregionalForeign assistance:Total postwar^---1962-66 average -.1966 i-<strong>Economic</strong> aid:Total postwarLoansGrants1962-65 averageLoans _Grants1966LoansGrantsAID and predecessor agencies:Total postwar1962-66 average ---.1966Food for Peace:Total postwar1962-66 average1966 —Export-Import Bank long-termloans:Total postwar—1962-65 average1966O<strong>the</strong>r economic aid: 3Total postwar1962-65 average1966Military assistance: *Total postwar 1LoansGrants1962-65 averageLoansGrants1966 1LoansGrantsAddendum—Repayments andinterest:«<strong>Economic</strong> assistance:Total postwar1962-65 average1966^Military assistance:Total postwar1962-65 average122,7936,3477,0232,0921,74618,73410,5378,1971,7541,2495051,4741,2502249,7268596227,08082082498868109407186,604630 1526,451338733127252671,626204315352445086,53034,84751,6834,7862,6522,1345,6163,1272,48942,5742,2422,54314,7551,6021,7262 9,4764882 79319,7254555531,561551,5061,408841,32413,1451,1471,22411,6771,2161,47310,6547,4143,2401,1267393871,3888685303,6585446471,6491892023,6801282261,7682663121,023144879907838530562,51924927528,2061,3742,05317,3563,07014,2867361955401,2622341,0289,3612,203252293976781094,8163725«10,849*10,813«639«98 630«790«7901181623,6354434123,4191,4731,9464191642553882021861,852223170977146142420314416919332161120624*242424327353547,1397016346,7995217055,5453595,186407193886351404942,74824426941851601661402,2131131651,2551601,09411413101713512412107 74167 11730,82211,99618,826344286584684412715,2293-12,5271452053,2471832639,8191416,31712716,19035619338166151517,5575294291 Includes preliminary 1966 military assistance date from <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Defense.2 Excludes $238 million in guaranteed loans purchased in 1966 and not distributed by country.3 Includes capital subscriptions to Inter-American Development Bank, International Bank for Reconstructionand Development, International Development Association, International Finance Corporation,and <strong>the</strong> Asian Development Bank (1946-66, $1,915 million; 1962-65 average, $179 million; 1966, $374 million)and Peace Corps (1962-66, $359 million; 1962-65 average, $62 million; 1966, $113 million).4 Includes grant-aid and credit assistance under <strong>the</strong> Foreign Assistance Act (FAA) plus military assistancegrants under o<strong>the</strong>r acts. FAA military data are from <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Defense. Annual data arefor deliveries. "Total postwar" entries are program totals.* Excludes Australia and New Zealand, shown in "o<strong>the</strong>r and nonregional."« Data for certain programs from Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce (Office <strong>of</strong> Business <strong>Economic</strong>s), and Department<strong>of</strong> Defense.Source: Agency for International Development (except as noted).310


TABLE B-84.-—International reserves, 1949, 1953, and 1961-66[Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars; end <strong>of</strong> period]Area and country1949196119621963196419651966SeptemberDecemberAll countriesDeveloped areasUnited StatesUnited KingdomSpainSwitzerlandO<strong>the</strong>rsCanadaJapanO<strong>the</strong>r Western Europe..AustriaBelgiumFranceGermanyItaly....,Ne<strong>the</strong>rlandsScandinavian countries(Denmark,Finland, Norway,and Sweden)Australia, New Zealand,and SouthAfricaLess developed areas *Latin America .Middle EastO<strong>the</strong>r Asia _.O<strong>the</strong>r Africa45,51537,24026,0241,7526,45592978580196( 2 )4345371*3431,197001,5828,2802,7751,4753,3953 29051,78041,39023,4582,67010.5153251,1448291,7737681,2321,0261501,7681,5001,9028921,95210,3903,4001,2003,8401,80062, 32053, 67018, 7533,31825,8138451,8133,3657,1633,7991,9581,6078862,7591,6182,2761,6661,8478,6502,6651,5052,8251,52562,62054, 23517, 2203,30826,9651,0811,7534,0496,9563,8181,9461,6101,0452,8721,8352,5472,0222,1758,3852,2001,7702,7801,55066,02056, 67516,8433,14729,2771,2291,9404,9087,6503,4062,1021,8751,1473,0781,9422,6032,0582,7489,3502,6852,2503,045'1,27068, 48058, 97016, 6722,31632,3101,3172,1925,7247,8823,8242,3492,3821,5133,1232,0042,8812,0192,7739,5102,8152,3152,9901,24569,84559, 06515, 4503,00433, 2251,3112,3046, 3437,4294,4152,4162,3261,4093,2472,0253,0272,1522,20510, 7803,2452,6903,3101,39070,30559,19014,8763,16133, 7941,3272,2946,8787,6724,5852,4092,3031,2762,9342,1152,7102,0892,55811,1202,9702,7453,7901,45514,8823,099134,4951,3332,3206,7338,0334,5662,4482,3421,2063,32712,1852,6832,1191 Estimate.2 Not available separately.8 In addition to o<strong>the</strong>r Western European countries, includes unpublished gold reserves <strong>of</strong> Greece andan estimate <strong>of</strong> gold to be distributed by <strong>the</strong> Tripartite Commission for <strong>the</strong> Restitution <strong>of</strong> MonetaryGold.• Includes unpublished gold holdings not allocable by area.NOTE.—Includes gold holdings, reserve positions in <strong>the</strong> International Monetary Fund, and foreign exchange<strong>of</strong> all countries except U.S.S.R., o<strong>the</strong>r Eastern European countries, Communist China, Cuba (afterMarch 1964), and Indonesia (after July 1965).Beginning 1959, when most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> major currencies <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> world became convertible, data exclude knownholdings <strong>of</strong> inconvertible currencies, balances under payments agreements, and <strong>the</strong> bilateral claims arisingfrom liquidation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> European Payments Union.Source: International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics.


TABLE B-85.—United States gold stock and holdings <strong>of</strong> convertible foreignmonetary authorities, 1946-66[Millions <strong>of</strong> dollars]currencies by U.S.End <strong>of</strong> year or monthTotalTotal aGold stock 1Treasury-Foreigncurrencyholdings194619471948194920,70622,86824,39924,56320,70622,86824,39924,56320,52922,75424,24424,427195019511952195319541955195619571958 -19591960196119621963196422,82022,87323,25222,09121,79321,75322,05822,85720,58219,50717,80417,06316,15615,80815,90322,82022,87323,25222,09121,79321, 75322,05822,85720, 58219,50717,80416,94716,05715,59615,47122,70622,69523,18722,03021,71321,69021,94922,78120,53419,45617,76716,88915,97815,51315,3881169921243219651966'1965: Jan..Feb..Mar.Apr.May.June.14,58714,55615,57215,22015,12914,88414,51114,59513,80613,23515,20814,99314,63914,48014,36214,04913,73313,15915,18514,93714,56314,41014,29013,9347811,321364227490404149546July.Aug.Sept.Oct...Nov.Dec.1966: Jan..Feb.Mar.Apr.May.June-July.Aug.Sept.Oct._Nov.Dec.14,69714,95314,88414,79514,68614,58714,45014,18814,29714,19014,21014,25114,50614,61814,50414,52414,37014,55613,96913,91613,92513,93713,87913,80613,81113,81113,73813,66813,58213,52913,41313,31913,35613,31113.26213,23513.85713,85713.85813,85713,80513,73313,73213,73013,63413,63213,53213,43313,33213,25913,25813,25713,15913,1597281,037959858807781639377559522628722:,299., 148,213,108,3211 Includes gold sold to <strong>the</strong> United States by <strong>the</strong> International Monetary Fund with <strong>the</strong> right <strong>of</strong> repurchase,which amounted to $800 million on December 31, 1966. Beginning September 1965 also includes gold depositedby <strong>the</strong> IMF to mitigate <strong>the</strong> impact on <strong>the</strong> U.S. gold stock <strong>of</strong> purchases by foreign countries for goldsubscriptions on increased IMF quotas. Amount outstanding was $211 million on Dec. 31, 1966. TheUnited States has a corresponding gold liability to <strong>the</strong> IMF.2 Includes gold in Exchange Stabilization Fund.NOTE.—Gold held under earmark at Federal Reserve Banks for foreign and international accounts is notincluded in <strong>the</strong> gold stock <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> United States.Sources: Treasury Department and Board <strong>of</strong> Governors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve System.312


TABLE B—86.—Price changes in international trade, 1958—66[1958=100]Area or commodity class 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 19651966ThirdquarterUnit value indexes by areaDeveloped areasTotal:ExportsTerms <strong>of</strong> trade i_United States 2ExportsTerms <strong>of</strong> trade 1Developing areasTotal:ExportsTerms <strong>of</strong> tradeLatin AmericaExportsTerms <strong>of</strong> trade !Latin America excluding petroleumExportsTerms <strong>of</strong> trade100100100100100100100100100100991021001029799959594941001031011019899959695961011041031059597939593951011051021079395919391921021041021059597949795103104103104979710110310497 10510410410610697971011021041051061043 1073 105973 1033 1033 1063 106World export price indexes 4Primary commodities: Total-10097979594100103100101FoodstuffsC<strong>of</strong>fee, tea, and cocoa-Cereals10010010093839791779690729890701031037310210687105998010110085106O<strong>the</strong>r agricultural commodities sFats, oils, and oilseeds.Textile fibersWool10088810510098106107941041081039710510799891011061039511212710598116131104108105110107106108119MineralsMetal ores.Nonferrous base metals.Manufactured goods *._.100100100100949711199939811410192100110102929910910292961101039410413510496110155106961081731091 Terms <strong>of</strong> trade indexes are unit value indexes <strong>of</strong> exports divided by unit value indexes <strong>of</strong> imports.2 Includes foreign trade <strong>of</strong> Alaska, Hawaii, and Puerto Rico.3 Data are for second quarter 1966.4 Data for manufactured goods are unit value indexes,s Includes nonfood fish and forest products.NOTE.—Data exclude trade <strong>of</strong> Communist areas in Eastern Europe (except Yugoslavia) and Asia.Sources: United Nations and Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce (Bureau <strong>of</strong> International Commerce).3*3


TABLE B—87.— Consumer price indexes in <strong>the</strong> United States and o<strong>the</strong>r major industrial countries,1955-66[1960=100]PeriodUnitedStatesCanadaJapanFranceGermanyItalyNe<strong>the</strong>rlandsUnitedKingdom19551956195719581959196019611962196319641965.196611964: I....II...III..IV..1965: I....II—III..IV..1966: I....II...III..IV 2.90.591.995.197.798.4100.0101.1102.2103.5104.9106.6109.7104.5104.7105.0105.4105.6106.4106.8107.4108.2109.3110.3111.290.992.395.297.798.8100.0100.9102.1103.9105.8108.4112.3105.0105.6106.2106.3107.2108.0108.9109.4110.9112.1113.1113.692.793.095.995.596.5100.0105.3112.5121.0125.6135.2142.2122.4125.1126.1128.8131.4136.0136.2137.3139.6142.7143.1144.275.576.979.090.996.5100. C103.3108.3113.5117.4120.3123.3116.3116.6117.5118.2119.1120.4120.6121.2122.2123.1123.8124.591.493.795.697.798.6100.0102.3105.4108.5111.1114.9118.8110.3110.9111.3111.8113.0114.4115.6116.2117.8119.2119.0119.391.294.395.598.297.8100.0102.1106.9114.8121.6127.1129.9119.1120.5122.5124.3125.7126.5127.7128.5129.4129.7130.1130.7888995979810010110310711311912611011411411411512012012012312812612687.892.195.698.599.0100.0103.4107.8110.0113.6119.0123.5111.3113.4114.3115.3116.4119.3119.8120.6121.4123.8124.2125.01 Eleven month average except United States. -2 For o<strong>the</strong>r than United States, data are averages <strong>of</strong> October and November.Sources: Department <strong>of</strong> Labor and Organization for <strong>Economic</strong> Cooperation and Development.314U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE: 1967O—240-782

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!