29.03.2013 Views

* Assistant Professor of Operations Management at INSEAD ...

* Assistant Professor of Operations Management at INSEAD ...

* Assistant Professor of Operations Management at INSEAD ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

This condition will usually not be fulfilled. If it is not fulfilled, then there<br />

is no customer differenti<strong>at</strong>ing equilibrium, because the firms have no way<br />

to distinguish the customers other than direct type identific<strong>at</strong>ion. Such a<br />

situ<strong>at</strong>ion is demonstr<strong>at</strong>ed in the following example.<br />

The market consists <strong>of</strong> 2 segments, with a high priority segment A and a<br />

low priority segment B. The groups are characterized by cA = 2 and pA = 5,<br />

whereas cB = 3 and fiB = 3. Thus cApA = 10 > 9 = cE4.43. Th<strong>at</strong> is, group A<br />

has the higher imp<strong>at</strong>ience-to-service time r<strong>at</strong>io, even though group B has a<br />

higher waiting cost r<strong>at</strong>e and is thus more imp<strong>at</strong>ient in the usual sense <strong>of</strong> the<br />

word. 2 The demand functions are PA(AA) = 1—A A and PB(AB) = 10-10AB.<br />

Thus, both groups are <strong>of</strong> the same size, but group B is more price sensitive<br />

and toler<strong>at</strong>es a higher maximum full price <strong>of</strong> 10.<br />

We insert these numbers into the formulae for the average delay and into<br />

the FOC, equ<strong>at</strong>ions (2), and we solve the FOC numerically. We find th<strong>at</strong><br />

in equilibrium each firm produces volumes <strong>of</strong> AA = 0.149 and AB = 0.292.<br />

These volumes result in prices <strong>of</strong> pA = 0.222 and pB = 3.015 and in delays<br />

<strong>of</strong> WA = 0.239 and WB = 0.379. The incentive comp<strong>at</strong>ibility condition<br />

requires th<strong>at</strong> pA > pB . However, type B customers end up paying more for<br />

inferior service! If the firms cannot identify customers upon placement <strong>of</strong> an<br />

order, type B customers see the chance <strong>of</strong> switching to lower price and faster<br />

delivery by lying about their type and subscribing as type A customers. The<br />

equilibrium breaks down. The market is unable to produce prices th<strong>at</strong> clear<br />

the quantities <strong>of</strong>fered by the two firms (who engage in quantity competition).<br />

Before I propose a contract th<strong>at</strong> restores the equilibrium, some remarks<br />

should illumin<strong>at</strong>e the circumstances under which it can occur th<strong>at</strong> the linear<br />

prices emerging from a full-inform<strong>at</strong>ion equilibrium are not incentive comp<strong>at</strong>ible.<br />

Inspection <strong>of</strong> the incentive-comp<strong>at</strong>ibility condition (4) reveals two<br />

types <strong>of</strong> situ<strong>at</strong>ions leading to incentive problems:<br />

1. The r<strong>at</strong>io c„ p„ is very high in comparison to some other type's cmitm<br />

because p 7, pm. In this case, the delivery time for m customers is<br />

very large by the sheer size <strong>of</strong> the raw service time, and this is not<br />

compens<strong>at</strong>ed for by a small waiting cost. Even though the cash price<br />

pm is not too large, the full price Pm is mainly driven by the waiting<br />

cost component and produces an incentive for type m customers to lie.<br />

2 Recall th<strong>at</strong> both firms have the same capacities, so the service r<strong>at</strong>es named above hold<br />

<strong>at</strong> both firms.<br />

11

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!