21.07.2013 Views

Figure 1: Motion Theory of Markets, Performance and Marketing ...

Figure 1: Motion Theory of Markets, Performance and Marketing ...

Figure 1: Motion Theory of Markets, Performance and Marketing ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Koen Pauwels Towards a <strong>Motion</strong> <strong>Theory</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Marketing</strong> 4/7/2004<br />

<strong>Figure</strong> 1: <strong>Motion</strong> <strong>Theory</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Markets</strong>, <strong>Performance</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Marketing</strong> Action<br />

Market Forces<br />

• Customer Learning<br />

<strong>and</strong> Imitation<br />

• Customer Inertia,<br />

Market Saturation<br />

• Supply Chain Actions<br />

• Socio-economic trends<br />

Pull in<br />

<strong>Motion</strong><br />

Put to<br />

Rest<br />

<strong>Performance</strong><br />

EVOLVING<br />

STABLE<br />

Offensive:<br />

Push in<br />

motion<br />

Defensive:<br />

Maintain<br />

Year after year, managers strive to improve their performance in ever changing<br />

markets. Faced with customer inertia, competitive reactions <strong>and</strong> market uncertainty, they<br />

are looking for marketing actions that yield long-term benefits to the company. CEO<br />

statements <strong>of</strong>ten reflect this rationale, in industries ranging from manufacturing 1 to<br />

services 2 to fast moving consumer goods 3 . Long-term marketing productivity permeates<br />

recent discussions on the pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong> Internet-based services, on downturn spending<br />

cuts, on building <strong>and</strong> maintaining br<strong>and</strong> equity, <strong>and</strong> on market entry strategies. The<br />

measurement <strong>and</strong> improvement <strong>of</strong> long-term financial returns to marketing investments<br />

continues as a top research priority <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Marketing</strong> Science Institute. Addressing this<br />

priority requires a dynamic underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the conditions for performance growth <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong> the role marketing actions play in this process. Existing theories <strong>of</strong> market dynamics,<br />

such as diffusion <strong>of</strong> innovation <strong>and</strong> life cycle theory, postulate deterministic changes over<br />

time, which are unrealistic in today’s uncertain market environments. Therefore, I<br />

propose a motion theory <strong>of</strong> marketing, as summarized in <strong>Figure</strong> 1.<br />

<strong>Marketing</strong> actions<br />

Market Entry (M&A)<br />

Positioning (STP)<br />

Product<br />

Price<br />

Distribution<br />

Communication<br />

1 Chrysler’s CEO Dieter Zetsche maintains that his forecasted sales gain <strong>of</strong> 1 million cars in the next 5 to<br />

10 years “will be driven by 12 new product introductions in the next three years rather than by low pricing”<br />

(J. D. Power <strong>and</strong> Associates 2002)<br />

2 In May 2001 (Wall Street Journal), America Online raised prices to meet its aggressive financial targets<br />

based on the company's confidence that the move would not compromise its growth in consumer base<br />

(164% since 1998) nor its growth in usage depth (52% since 1998). Bold? Maybe. Unwise? Certainly.<br />

3 Despite saturated dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> strong competition, "Coke is sticking by its ambitious growth targets <strong>and</strong><br />

believes that they can be reached "over the long-term” (Wall Street Journal, November 16, 1999)<br />

1


Koen Pauwels Towards a <strong>Motion</strong> <strong>Theory</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Marketing</strong> 4/7/2004<br />

Basic Elements <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Motion</strong> <strong>Theory</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Marketing</strong><br />

Application <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Motion</strong> <strong>Theory</strong> requires us to answer a few questions:<br />

1) The <strong>Performance</strong> Question: where are we heading, what is the long-term outlook?<br />

General answer: “baseline” forecasting as backbone <strong>of</strong> management action planning.<br />

<strong>Motion</strong> answer: identify <strong>and</strong> analyze performance regimes (see p. 3, <strong>and</strong> Pauwels 2001)<br />

2) Pr<strong>of</strong>itable Growth Question: Are we satisfied or not with were we are going?<br />

General answer: If so, don’t do anything (management by exception or thermostat), if<br />

not, use marketing actions to close gap between desired future <strong>and</strong> baseline performance<br />

<strong>Motion</strong> answer: If so, continue to pump the market for temporary, but pr<strong>of</strong>itable benefits<br />

(e.g. price promotions or minor product modifications). If not, a marketing policy change<br />

is needed to push performance into motion (see p. 5). Business as usual just won’t do.<br />

3) <strong>Marketing</strong> Question: how to change our destiny; how to improve where we are going? 4<br />

General answer: increase marketing actions with the best “bang-for-your-buck”, i.e.<br />

combining high performance impact (elasticity) with cost efficiency. <strong>Performance</strong><br />

benefits are typically estimated by a static model such as regression, logit, etc.<br />

<strong>Motion</strong> answer: The needed policy changes may differ from marketing actions with the<br />

highest elasticity <strong>and</strong> efficiency in stationary regimes <strong>and</strong> their long-term costs (including<br />

competitive reaction <strong>and</strong> needed maintenance spending) should be weighted against their<br />

long-term benefits: pushing performance towards a more favorable regime (see p. 5-6)<br />

t 4 A trend is a trend, is a trend, but the question is, will it bend?<br />

Will it alter its course, through some unforeseen force, <strong>and</strong> come to a premature end?<br />

Sir Alec Cairncross, chief economic advisor to the British government<br />

2


Koen Pauwels Towards a <strong>Motion</strong> <strong>Theory</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Marketing</strong> 4/7/2004<br />

<strong>Performance</strong> Regimes<br />

<strong>Performance</strong> regimes can readily be classified by their managerial desirability, based<br />

on two dimensions: the direction <strong>of</strong> change (i.e. growth is better than stagnation, which is<br />

better than decline), <strong>and</strong> the uncertainty around this change (i.e. lower uncertainty is<br />

better than high uncertainty for improving conditions, <strong>and</strong> vice versa). Modern time-<br />

series analysis can diagnose direction as well as uncertainty: a deterministic trend reveals<br />

the direction <strong>of</strong> change, <strong>and</strong> a stochastic trend reveals the uncertainty around the future<br />

direction <strong>of</strong> performance. If there is no stochastic trend, then performance is stationary,<br />

i.e. all observed fluctuations are temporary deviations from a deterministic component,<br />

which may include mean, trend <strong>and</strong> seasonal cycles. Stationary behavior implies that<br />

future performance is relatively predictable, as the expected forecasting error gently<br />

increases with the forecast horizon. In contrast, the presence <strong>of</strong> a stochastic trend or unit<br />

root implies that sales performance may move widely apart from any previously observed<br />

level, with a variance that increases in time.<br />

Table 1: Classification <strong>of</strong> performance regimes, ordered by managerial desirability<br />

Deterministic trend<br />

Stochastic trend<br />

Stationary Evolving<br />

Positive Deterministic Growth (#1) Stochastic Growth (#2)<br />

None Static Equilibrium (#3) R<strong>and</strong>om Walk (#4)<br />

Negative Deterministic Decline (#6) Stochastic Decline (#5)<br />

3


Koen Pauwels Towards a <strong>Motion</strong> <strong>Theory</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Marketing</strong> 4/7/2004<br />

Table 1 combines the managerial desirability <strong>of</strong> a performance regime with observable<br />

conditions in the data. Deterministic growth (#1) <strong>and</strong> decline (#6) are, respectively, the<br />

best <strong>and</strong> worst-case scenarios. <strong>Performance</strong> evolution adds uncertainty <strong>and</strong> therefore<br />

attenuates the good news <strong>and</strong> the bad news. Finally, in the case <strong>of</strong> no deterministic trend,<br />

risk-averse managers typically prefer a static equilibrium above a r<strong>and</strong>om walk.<br />

When would we expect to observe performance stability <strong>and</strong> evolution? Table 2 lists<br />

several factors outside <strong>and</strong> inside the control <strong>of</strong> market players (firms <strong>and</strong> consumers).<br />

Table 2: Reasons for evolution <strong>and</strong> stability in performance<br />

Evolution Stability<br />

Co-movements <strong>of</strong> performance with<br />

macro-economic variables<br />

Growth stage in the product life cycle<br />

Changing marketing effectiveness<br />

Consumer learning<br />

Changing consumer tastes<br />

I. Factors outside the control <strong>of</strong> the market players<br />

Positive feedback sales & retail distribution<br />

<strong>Performance</strong> feedback<br />

Error-correction towards performance goal<br />

Competitive quest for more in budgeting<br />

Breakthrough changes in marketing<br />

strategy or practices, which are not quickly<br />

matched by competitors<br />

Government regulations that limit company<br />

growth <strong>and</strong>/or bankruptcy options<br />

Maturity stage in the product life cycle<br />

Stable marketing effectiveness<br />

II. Behavior <strong>of</strong> consumers <strong>and</strong> retailers<br />

Consumer Forgetting<br />

Consumer inertia<br />

III. Management decision making<br />

Retailer inertia & assortment commitment<br />

Normative marketing decision models<br />

Satisficing managers<br />

Fixing marketing budgets as sales ratios<br />

Interdependent adaptation with competitors<br />

enables fast competitive cancellation <strong>of</strong><br />

marketing effects<br />

4


Koen Pauwels Towards a <strong>Motion</strong> <strong>Theory</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Marketing</strong> 4/7/2004<br />

Research postulates (RP) <strong>and</strong> marketing spending (MS) rules<br />

RP 1: <strong>Performance</strong> Evolution occurs in specific time windows between stable regimes<br />

Why? Stability is the natural state <strong>of</strong> the market performance because <strong>of</strong> consumer habit<br />

persistence / inertia <strong>and</strong> competitive vigilance.<br />

MS rule 1: your budget allocation should vary with the growth path <strong>of</strong> performance<br />

RP 2: In mature markets, these evolution periods are short relative to the stable periods<br />

Why? Punctuated equilibrium theory applies to markets: you can only change customer<br />

behavior in a few short-lived circumstances that engage customer learning, before<br />

customer inertia, market saturation <strong>and</strong>/or effective competitive reaction make this<br />

growth grind to a halt.<br />

MS rule 2: use your money first on marketing actions that co-evolve with outcome series<br />

RP 3: <strong>Marketing</strong> actions <strong>and</strong> policy shifts have different effects on performance regimes<br />

Why? In stable performance regimes, you can continuously improve marketing efficiency<br />

<strong>and</strong> perceived customer value by product modifications, price promotions, point-<strong>of</strong>-<br />

purchase efforts <strong>and</strong> reminder advertising. However, these business-as-usual marketing<br />

actions do not have the power to put performance in motion towards a better regime.<br />

If you want to push performance in motion, you need a change in marketing policy. A<br />

major new product introduction, a sustained price decrease, a new distribution channel<br />

<strong>and</strong> innovative advertising have the potential to push performance in evolution <strong>and</strong> create<br />

permanent effects by enabling performance to stabilize at a new, higher equilibrium level.<br />

MS Rule 4: marketing policy shifts are needed to push stable performance into motion<br />

5


Koen Pauwels Towards a <strong>Motion</strong> <strong>Theory</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Marketing</strong> 4/7/2004<br />

RP 4: Return on <strong>Marketing</strong> Investment differs in different performance regimes<br />

Why? Unexpected actions that disrupt consumer expectations <strong>and</strong> habits are possible, but<br />

hard to pull <strong>of</strong>f: they <strong>of</strong>ten require creative, integrated <strong>and</strong> expensive marketing changes.<br />

However, when performance is already evolving, i.e. consumers or retailers are learning,<br />

usual marketing actions may help push it along. For instance, printer manufacturers enjoy<br />

permanent advertising effects when their product is clearly superior to the competition.<br />

MS Rule 4: focus your marketing efforts to lift performance that is already evolving<br />

References<br />

Academic references were omitted for readability; they can all be found in:<br />

Pauwels, Koen (2001), Long-Term <strong>Marketing</strong> Effectiveness in Mature, Emerging <strong>and</strong><br />

Changing <strong>Markets</strong>, Ph.D. Dissertation, The Anderson Graduate School <strong>of</strong> Management,<br />

University <strong>of</strong> California, Los Angeles.<br />

6

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!