25.07.2013 Views

Regional Integration and Trade in Agrifood Products: - DAAD ...

Regional Integration and Trade in Agrifood Products: - DAAD ...

Regional Integration and Trade in Agrifood Products: - DAAD ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Regional</strong> <strong>Integration</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Agrifood</strong><br />

<strong>Products</strong>:<br />

Evidence from the East African Community<br />

By<br />

Francis Ejones<br />

November, 2012


Abstract<br />

This study exam<strong>in</strong>es the postulation that trade liberalization (regional <strong>in</strong>tegration) policies of<br />

LDCs normally underm<strong>in</strong>e their presumed impact. The study is based on the experience of EAC<br />

trade agreement. It adopts the extended gravity model, to analyze the impact of this regional<br />

<strong>in</strong>tegration on food item. The model <strong>in</strong>cludes 168 countries <strong>and</strong> is estimated with panel data over<br />

the period 1988 – 1996. The Poisson estimation method took <strong>in</strong>to account unobserved trade data<br />

characteristics of the bilateral trade relations. The results show that regional trade <strong>in</strong>tegration<br />

<strong>in</strong>creased exports, normally at the expense of exports <strong>and</strong> welfare of non-members, <strong>and</strong> these<br />

exports were more reflective of food exports growth. The same has not been true for <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc<br />

exports of food although the sector experienced an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> exports result<strong>in</strong>g from the<br />

implementation of a trade agreement. The <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc results are consistent with the structural<br />

rigidities of the export<strong>in</strong>g EAC Countries.<br />

Keywords: <strong>Regional</strong> <strong>Integration</strong>, <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Agrifood</strong> or Food Items or <strong>Products</strong>, EAC, Gravity<br />

Model <strong>and</strong> Poisson, Panel Data Analysis.<br />

Characters: 28,032<br />

ii


Table of Content<br />

Abstract ................................................................................................................................................... ii<br />

List of Notations ................................................................................................................................. vi<br />

Acknowledgment............................................................................................................................... vii<br />

CHAPTER ONE ..................................................................................................................................... 1<br />

1.0 Introduction ............................................................................................................................. 1<br />

1.1 The Subject of the Study .......................................................................................................... 1<br />

1.2 Statement of the Research Problem .......................................................................................... 2<br />

1.3 The Purpose <strong>and</strong> Research Questions Tackled <strong>in</strong> the Study ....................................................... 3<br />

1.4 Relevance to the Field of International Economics.................................................................... 3<br />

1.5 Brief Description of the Methodology ...................................................................................... 4<br />

1.6 Scope of the Study ................................................................................................................... 5<br />

1.7 Types <strong>and</strong> Sources of Data ....................................................................................................... 5<br />

1.8 Delimitations of the Study ........................................................................................................ 5<br />

1.9 Organization of the Study ......................................................................................................... 6<br />

Chapter Two ........................................................................................................................................... 8<br />

2.0 Background to the EAC <strong>and</strong> Food Item <strong>Trade</strong> ........................................................................... 8<br />

2.1 Evolution of EAC: From Cooperation to Common Market <strong>and</strong> Beyond .................................... 8<br />

2.2 EAC Food <strong>and</strong> Agricultural Program ...................................................................................... 14<br />

2.2.1 Prom<strong>in</strong>ence of Food <strong>and</strong> Agriculture <strong>in</strong> EAC Common Market Protocol. ........................ 14<br />

2.2.2 Treatment of Agriculture <strong>in</strong> the EAC Common Protocol (Article 105 – 110) ................... 15<br />

2.3 Inter - Sectoral Trends <strong>and</strong> Structure of the Selected Exports of the EAC................................ 16<br />

2.3.1 EAC Export Trends <strong>and</strong> its Constitution by Product. ....................................................... 16<br />

iii


2.3.2 EAC Member States Contribution to Export of the Selected <strong>Products</strong> ............................. 17<br />

Figure 2.2 Relative Contributions of EAC Member States to the <strong>Trade</strong> of Selected <strong>Products</strong> .............. 18<br />

2.3.3 Country Decomposition of EAC Exports by Sector ......................................................... 18<br />

2.3.4 Sectoral Decomposition of EAC Exports by Country ...................................................... 23<br />

2.4 Intra – Sectoral Trends <strong>and</strong> Structure of the Selected Exports of the EAC ............................... 26<br />

2.4.1 Intra - EAC Export Trends <strong>and</strong> its Constitution by Product. ............................................ 26<br />

2.4.2 Intra-EAC Member States Contribution to Export of the Selected <strong>Products</strong> ..................... 27<br />

2.4.3 Country Decomposition of EAC Exports by Sector ......................................................... 28<br />

2.4.4 Sectoral Decomposition of Intra - EAC Exports by Country ............................................ 31<br />

Chapter Three ........................................................................................................................................ 35<br />

3.0 Literature Review ................................................................................................................... 35<br />

3.1 Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 35<br />

3.2 Review of Def<strong>in</strong>itional Issues ................................................................................................. 35<br />

3.2.1 Def<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>and</strong> Measurement of the Effects of EI or RTAs .............................................. 35<br />

3.2.2 Def<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>and</strong> Measurement of <strong>Agrifood</strong> or Food Items ................................................. 37<br />

3.2.3 Def<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>and</strong> Specification Issues of Gravity ................................................................ 38<br />

3.3 Review of Theoretical Issues .................................................................................................. 38<br />

3.3.1 Classical or Traditional Theories of International <strong>Trade</strong> .................................................. 39<br />

3.3.1.1 Mercantilist Theory of International <strong>Trade</strong> ...................................................................... 40<br />

3.3.1.2 Absolute Advantage <strong>and</strong> Comparative Advantage Theory of International <strong>Trade</strong> ................ 40<br />

3.3.2 Neo-Classical or St<strong>and</strong>ard <strong>Trade</strong> Theories ...................................................................... 42<br />

3.3.3 New <strong>Trade</strong> Theories <strong>and</strong> new development <strong>in</strong> Analyz<strong>in</strong>g International <strong>Trade</strong> .................. 42<br />

3.4 Review of Theoretical Foundation of Gravity Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>Trade</strong>. .......................................... 44<br />

3.5 Review of Methodological <strong>and</strong> Empirical Issues ..................................................................... 45<br />

3.6 Conclusion <strong>and</strong> Relevance of the Literature Review ............................................................... 46<br />

Chapter Four ......................................................................................................................................... 48<br />

4.0 Analytical Framework <strong>and</strong> Methodology ................................................................................ 48<br />

4.1 Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 48<br />

4.2 Analytical Framework: Gravity Model ................................................................................... 48<br />

4.3 Specification of Empirical Equations ...................................................................................... 49<br />

4.3.1 Coefficients <strong>and</strong> Variable Def<strong>in</strong>ition ............................................................................... 50<br />

4.4 Method of Analysis ................................................................................................................ 54<br />

iv


4.5 Type <strong>and</strong> Sources of Data ....................................................................................................... 55<br />

Chapter Five .......................................................................................................................................... 57<br />

5.0 Presentation <strong>and</strong> Discussion of Empirical Results ................................................................... 57<br />

5.1 Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 57<br />

5.2 Descriptive Statistics .............................................................................................................. 58<br />

5.2.1 Summary Statistics ......................................................................................................... 58<br />

5.2.2 Regression Correlation Matrix ........................................................................................ 59<br />

5.2.3 Assessment of the Model Us<strong>in</strong>g the Observed Versus Predicted Values .......................... 60<br />

5.2.4 Test for Normality .......................................................................................................... 60<br />

5.3 Regression Diagnostics .......................................................................................................... 62<br />

5.3.1 Test<strong>in</strong>g for Homoscedasticity ......................................................................................... 62<br />

5.3.2 Test<strong>in</strong>g for Multicoll<strong>in</strong>earity ........................................................................................... 63<br />

5.4 Presentation of Estimates <strong>and</strong> Discussion of Results ............................................................... 64<br />

5.4.1 Summary of Econometrics Methods ............................................................................... 64<br />

5.4.2 Results of the Determ<strong>in</strong>ants of Exports of EAC .............................................................. 66<br />

5.4.3 Application to the assessment of the effects of regional trade agreements. ....................... 68<br />

5.4.3 Application to the sectoral assessment of the effects of the adopted sectors ..................... 69<br />

Chapter Six ........................................................................................................................................... 71<br />

6.0 Summary, Conclusion <strong>and</strong> Policy Recommendations.............................................................. 71<br />

6.1 Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 71<br />

6.2 Summary of the Empirical Analysis ....................................................................................... 71<br />

6.4 Policy Recommendations ....................................................................................................... 75<br />

References............................................................................................................................................. 77<br />

Appendix A: List of Tables ................................................................................................................ 81<br />

Appendix B: Correlation Matrix ........................................................................................................ 85<br />

Appendix C: Estimation Results from Gravity ................................................................................... 86<br />

v


List of Notations<br />

AoA - Agreement on Agriculture<br />

APEC - Asia-Pacific Economic Commission<br />

CET - Common External Tariff<br />

CGE - Computable General Equilibrium<br />

COMESA - Common Market for East <strong>and</strong> Southern Africa<br />

DDA - Doha Development Agenda<br />

EAC - East African Community<br />

EASRA - East African Securities Regulatory Authorities<br />

EU - European Union<br />

FDI - Foreign Direct Investments<br />

Mercusor - Lat<strong>in</strong> American Common Markets<br />

MUBS - Makerere University Bus<strong>in</strong>ess School<br />

NAFTA - North American Free <strong>Trade</strong> Area<br />

NBER - The National Bureau of Economic Research<br />

OECD - Organization of Economic Cooperation <strong>and</strong> Development<br />

OLS - Ord<strong>in</strong>ary Least Squares<br />

PWT - Penn World Tables<br />

RTAs - <strong>Regional</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> Agreement(s)<br />

SAPTA - South Asian Association for <strong>Regional</strong> Cooperation<br />

SIDA - Swedish International Development Cooperation Agency<br />

S-S - South South<br />

TRAPCA - <strong>Trade</strong> Policy Research Centre <strong>in</strong> Africa<br />

UN-ESCAP - United Nations Economic <strong>and</strong> Social Commission for Asia <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Pacific<br />

UR - Uruguay Round<br />

Vi/UNCTAD - Virtual Institute of the United Nations Conference on <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

Development<br />

WITS - World Integrated <strong>Trade</strong> System<br />

WTO - World <strong>Trade</strong> Organization<br />

vi


Acknowledgment<br />

I am grateful for comments on the drafts of this paper provided by Prof. Dr. Göte Hansson,<br />

Dr.Wumi Kalawole, <strong>and</strong> Dr. Caiaphas Chekwoti.<br />

The conviction of writ<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> analyz<strong>in</strong>g a panel dataset on EAC was provided by Dr. Marco<br />

Fugaaza. He also endeared upon me to construct a large dataset such as the one used <strong>in</strong> this study<br />

<strong>and</strong> guided me <strong>in</strong> the tedious process of its construction. I also benefitted a lot from the classes<br />

on panel data <strong>and</strong> STATA that he h<strong>and</strong>led <strong>in</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a under the auspices of the Virtual Institute<br />

of United Nations Conference on <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>and</strong> Development(VI-UNCTAD) <strong>and</strong> Makerere<br />

University Bus<strong>in</strong>ess School (MUBS). Joshua Kayiwa, Richard Sebaggala <strong>and</strong> Kenneth Jumanyol<br />

whose advice guided me on how to proceed with tricky STATA <strong>and</strong> panel estimation processes.<br />

Special thanks to the Vi UNCTAD <strong>and</strong> especially Dr. Vlasta Macku for provid<strong>in</strong>g me an<br />

opportunity to develop the orig<strong>in</strong>al ideas of this paper. The text was edited by Eng<strong>in</strong>eer Samuel<br />

Odora.<br />

The f<strong>in</strong>ancial support of my family <strong>and</strong> SIDA under the Lund University/TRAPCA is<br />

gratefully acknowledged.<br />

vii


1.0 Introduction<br />

CHAPTER ONE<br />

1.1 The Subject of the Study<br />

The Agreement on Agriculture (AoA),a product of the Uruguay Round (UR)<br />

<strong>in</strong>troduced a significant departure from the traditional treatment of agriculture<br />

multilaterally (OECD 1997). It extended the basic pr<strong>in</strong>ciples <strong>and</strong> commitments <strong>in</strong><br />

market access, export competition <strong>and</strong> domestic support (Kessie 2004 <strong>and</strong> OECD<br />

1997). The prescience on the modest ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> agriculture (<strong>and</strong> services) called for<br />

further negotiations after the implementation of the UR <strong>in</strong> order to improve the<br />

results <strong>in</strong> these areas (Kessie 2004). The built-<strong>in</strong> agenda <strong>in</strong> these agreements was<br />

brought under a new round of negotiations known as the Doha Development Agenda<br />

(DDA). Thatwas deemed to provide greater economic opportunities to develop<strong>in</strong>g<br />

countries. However, the round of negotiations under the DDA have lurched past the<br />

set deadl<strong>in</strong>es of its conclusion because of the differ<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terests of member countries<br />

<strong>and</strong> country group<strong>in</strong>gs, <strong>in</strong>ter alia, <strong>in</strong> domestic support, special safeguards <strong>and</strong><br />

designation of special products. The bog <strong>in</strong> reach<strong>in</strong>g consensus (especially on<br />

agriculture) has generated pessimistic perceptions of the effectiveness of the WTO.<br />

Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries (<strong>and</strong> particularly the least developed among them), believe<br />

that the agricultural reforms proposed by developed countries were too limited. To<br />

hasten commitment <strong>in</strong> agriculture <strong>and</strong> consolidate significant achievements <strong>in</strong> the<br />

area <strong>and</strong> other contentious sectors, groups of countries have resorted to regional trade<br />

agreements (RTAs) (Head <strong>and</strong> Ries, 2004).<br />

With this grow<strong>in</strong>g development, nation states embarked on an accelerated trend<br />

towards form<strong>in</strong>g regional <strong>and</strong>preferential bilateral trade agreements <strong>in</strong> every part of<br />

the world 1 . These proliferations exude an <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g level of sophistication, both <strong>in</strong><br />

terms of scope <strong>and</strong> configuration than ever experienced before. In terms of<br />

sophistication of configurations, the South-South (S-S) <strong>in</strong>tegration is seen as one of<br />

the most dazzl<strong>in</strong>g. More to this, agriculture plays an important <strong>and</strong> tw<strong>in</strong> part <strong>in</strong> the S-<br />

S cooperation <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>tegration blocs. It is significant for exports <strong>and</strong> essential for<br />

1 See VI-UNCTAD Teach<strong>in</strong>g Material on RTAs (2007).<br />

1


<strong>in</strong>tra-bloc trad<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> merch<strong>and</strong>ise. S-S <strong>in</strong>tra-<strong>and</strong>-<strong>in</strong>ter bloc markets provide a scope<br />

for maximiz<strong>in</strong>g ga<strong>in</strong>s from trad<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> food <strong>and</strong> agriculture raw materials. This is<br />

attributed to improved markets access policies <strong>and</strong> implementation of <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc<br />

production support much faster <strong>and</strong> readily, than it would be at the <strong>in</strong>ternational level.<br />

Auxiliary, processed merch<strong>and</strong>ise (especially agriculture <strong>and</strong> food products) from S-S<br />

countries have faced higher tariffs for a specific range of products of major <strong>in</strong>terest to<br />

these periphery states. Besides this, there are other restrictions related to st<strong>and</strong>ards<br />

that bar them from export<strong>in</strong>g agricultural products, especially, to the lucrative<br />

markets <strong>in</strong> the North.<br />

However, there is a scare at the scope <strong>and</strong> speed of trade liberalization of the food<br />

sector on the one side, <strong>and</strong> this liberalization <strong>in</strong> relation to other sectors such as<br />

agricultural raw materials, fuels, ores <strong>and</strong> metals, <strong>and</strong> manufactures on the other side.<br />

The liberalization measures <strong>in</strong> the food or even agricultural sectors <strong>in</strong>hibited efforts to<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc trade <strong>and</strong> underm<strong>in</strong>e food security rather than uplift efforts to<br />

reduce poverty as Vylder (2007) argues.<br />

It is statements <strong>and</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs there<strong>in</strong> that have bred <strong>in</strong>terest to f<strong>in</strong>d out whether the<br />

efforts of the East African Community (EAC) are pay<strong>in</strong>g off, s<strong>in</strong>ce the bloc‟s<br />

ambition <strong>in</strong> secur<strong>in</strong>g the ga<strong>in</strong>s are commendable. Among the S-S blocs, EAC member<br />

states have exuded the fastest <strong>and</strong> most significant liberalization measures, <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>curred huge sunk costs <strong>in</strong> reconfigur<strong>in</strong>g the bloc from an FTA to now a common<br />

market <strong>in</strong> less than 10 years. It is hoped to become a political federation (the highest<br />

<strong>and</strong> most complex level of <strong>in</strong>tegration) by 2015. However, a survey of the literature<br />

on RTAs hardly reveals any empirical literature on EAC to solve such empirical<br />

<strong>in</strong>terest <strong>and</strong> it has neglected trade <strong>in</strong> food item.<br />

1.2 Statement of the Research Problem<br />

The massive changes <strong>and</strong> commitments <strong>in</strong> EAC food or agrifood sector was <strong>and</strong> is<br />

presumed to impact significantly on <strong>Agrifood</strong> trade <strong>in</strong> the region. The extent to which<br />

these policies have impacted on agrifood trade is however not known or even<br />

documented. This could possibly be due to limited <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>adequate empirical studies<br />

guid<strong>in</strong>g the evolution of the EAC <strong>and</strong> the process of formulat<strong>in</strong>g its policies. The<br />

limited studies are also ta<strong>in</strong>ted with strong statements, theory <strong>and</strong> causal empiricism<br />

rather than robust empirical studies <strong>and</strong> theories. Studies like Wanjiru, (2006);<br />

Gregory, (1981); Kirkpatrick <strong>and</strong> Wantabe (2005); Ochwada, (2004) written on EAC,<br />

are too general to answer the pert<strong>in</strong>ent issues evolv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the bloc, <strong>and</strong> as such, are<br />

devoid of their explicit policy outcomes <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>tention to guide sectoral or specific<br />

policy needs of the bloc. Studies on RTAs, though exclusive of EAC dynamics have<br />

2


also not paid attention to the effects orimpacts of these trad<strong>in</strong>g blocs on agrifood<br />

trade, a core area that this study tackles. The methodologies <strong>and</strong> econometric<br />

processes adopted by these studies have even most times been spurious. The data was<br />

not as disaggregated as the one this study utilized. In this regard, the unanswered<br />

questions <strong>in</strong>clude: Are the EAC trade liberalization efforts bear<strong>in</strong>g fruit for the bloc,<br />

<strong>and</strong> chang<strong>in</strong>g the structure of its <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc sectoral trade especially <strong>in</strong> food or<br />

agrifood trade? Is the volume of its <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc trade <strong>in</strong> agrifood trade improv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong><br />

how is this decomposed by country?<br />

1.3 The Purpose <strong>and</strong> Research Questions Tackled <strong>in</strong> the<br />

Study<br />

The study analyzes the effect of EAC trade liberalization policies on <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc trade<br />

of selected sectors with food item trade as the reference sub-sector. This is because<br />

trade liberalization experience of least develop<strong>in</strong>g countries has underm<strong>in</strong>ed their<br />

presumed impact as argued by Vylder (2007), <strong>and</strong> hence bred empirical <strong>in</strong>terest.<br />

The ma<strong>in</strong>questionsraised <strong>in</strong> this thesis are as follows:<br />

Does the adopted trade liberalization policy expla<strong>in</strong> bloc trade? What are the<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>ants,<strong>and</strong> estimatesof the EAC trade at both the regional <strong>and</strong> at country<br />

levels?<br />

To what extent has the EAC trade liberalization efforts affected its <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc<br />

trad<strong>in</strong>g patterns of the selected sectors?<br />

What is the impact of EAC trade liberalization on <strong>in</strong>tra-regional exports<br />

<strong>and</strong>their implication on trade creation <strong>and</strong> trade diversion?<br />

1.4 Relevance to the Field of International Economics<br />

EAC is develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> transform<strong>in</strong>g at a remarkable rate. With<strong>in</strong> ten years, the bloc<br />

has <strong>in</strong>creased its membership to five from three, <strong>and</strong> transformed from a Customs<br />

Union to a Common Market. With<strong>in</strong> the next four years, it will be elevated to a<br />

monetary Union <strong>in</strong> 2012 <strong>and</strong> Political Federation by 2014. The surge to liberalize is<br />

also emanat<strong>in</strong>g from pressure from developed nations like European Community<br />

countries to actualize these developments. What seem to guide the reform are strong<br />

political statements, theory <strong>and</strong> causal empiricism rather than logical economic<br />

rationale. This study <strong>in</strong> part attempts to provide a more grounded analysis to guide<br />

this process. It also tackled <strong>and</strong> focused on agrifood sector analysis, a sub sector<br />

3


hardly be<strong>in</strong>g studied. Therefore, the outcome of this study will provide background<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation for the policy formation process.<br />

Theoretically, the study tests <strong>and</strong> utilizes the new theoretical improvements <strong>in</strong> the<br />

gravity model, deal<strong>in</strong>g with the treatment of trade, robustness, <strong>and</strong> zero trade issues<br />

etc. And on the methodological ground <strong>and</strong> empirical frontier, it expounds on the use<br />

of gravity model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> utilizes it for EAC, a trad<strong>in</strong>g bloc that has not been<br />

empirically explored well.<br />

1.5 Brief Description of the Methodology<br />

A variant of material, <strong>in</strong> terms of eccentricity <strong>and</strong> content has been adopted <strong>and</strong><br />

utilized to write this study. Cont<strong>in</strong>uums of authors have had <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> analyz<strong>in</strong>g<br />

RTAs <strong>in</strong> general <strong>and</strong> EAC bloc <strong>in</strong> particular. They have ma<strong>in</strong>ly approached the<br />

analysis from a political economy <strong>and</strong> economic angle of analysis. This study utilized<br />

the economic approach for its analysis. The political economy approach has been<br />

discarded from the discussion as far as possible. Simply because it is not of <strong>in</strong>terest to<br />

this study, as it fails to answer the pert<strong>in</strong>ent questions that the study proposes.<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ce the Uruguay Round, the basic pr<strong>in</strong>ciples <strong>and</strong> commitments <strong>in</strong> the treatment<br />

of agriculture has significantly re-oriented the treatment of agriculture. However, the<br />

lack of progress <strong>in</strong> core areas <strong>in</strong> agriculture has propelled the evolution of RTAs <strong>in</strong><br />

which food item or agrifood trade is important for food security <strong>and</strong> poverty<br />

eradication. Literature of the key issues relat<strong>in</strong>g to the evidence of the impact of these<br />

developments fall <strong>in</strong> the writ<strong>in</strong>g found <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational trade, political economy, etc.<br />

The literature is well developed <strong>and</strong> documented <strong>in</strong> text books, journal articles,<br />

articles <strong>and</strong> comments found variously.<br />

Among the economic approaches or methodologies of analysis are; descriptive,<br />

Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) <strong>and</strong> econometric approaches. However, this<br />

study adopted the descriptive approaches <strong>and</strong> econometric approach to analyze the<br />

effects of the adopted policies. In the descriptive approach, a critical analysis of the<br />

data <strong>and</strong> documentation was garnered. An analytical approach augmented from the<br />

theoretical approach was contextualized. The analytical approach adopted <strong>in</strong>volved<br />

augment<strong>in</strong>g the traditional gravity model with covariates to estimate <strong>and</strong> answer the<br />

pert<strong>in</strong>ent questions <strong>in</strong> the study. A panel dataset of 22 years from 1988 to 2009, with<br />

168 countries <strong>and</strong> five products of key <strong>in</strong>terest to EAC was utilized.<br />

4


1.6 Scope of the Study<br />

The study adopts a gravity model estimation procedure with disaggregated data to<br />

analyze effects of EAC on selected major agrifood products <strong>in</strong> relation to four other<br />

sectors (Agricultural raw materials, ores <strong>and</strong> metals, fuels <strong>and</strong> manufactured goods).<br />

The data for the study runs from 1988 to 2009 for all the products <strong>and</strong> bilateral<br />

relations between the EAC member states <strong>and</strong> their trad<strong>in</strong>g partners. And an extended<br />

gravity model is used to determ<strong>in</strong>e the extent of <strong>in</strong>traregional trade bias <strong>and</strong> potential<br />

trade diversion effects for the selected commodities separately. A panel regression is<br />

estimated us<strong>in</strong>g generalized least squares method for the period under consideration<br />

(1988 to 2009). This period is adopted due to the availability of a complete dataset for<br />

all countries for all the period.<br />

1.7 Types <strong>and</strong> Sources of Data<br />

There are broadly two categories of data. One is qualitative <strong>and</strong> the other is<br />

quantitative. S<strong>in</strong>ce the bulk of the data analyzed <strong>in</strong> this study is numerical <strong>in</strong> form,<br />

the quantitative data type was used. To the greatest extent possible, qualitative data<br />

type was relegated. Where it was available, the qualitative attributes if the data were<br />

coded, hence mak<strong>in</strong>g them quantitative.<br />

The source of these quantitative type depended on the variable. However, three<br />

major sources were used to collect the data. The first set of data was the trade data<br />

collected from the World Integrated <strong>Trade</strong> Solutions (WITS) of the United Nations.<br />

The second source of data was from the World Penn Tables (WPT 7.0). Data from<br />

the WPT relates a set of national accounts economic time series cover<strong>in</strong>g many<br />

countries. And the third source of data was m<strong>in</strong>ed from CEPII. CEPII data related to<br />

countries <strong>and</strong> their ma<strong>in</strong> city or agglomeration.<br />

1.8 Delimitations of the Study<br />

An attempt to estimate the impact of myriad of aspects of a regional bloc like EAC <strong>in</strong><br />

a s<strong>in</strong>gle study like this is a daunt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> unfeasible task. A study cover<strong>in</strong>g the wide<br />

range of details to fit such studies would necessitate rigorous <strong>and</strong> broad research.<br />

Further, it would require time, personnel <strong>and</strong> substantial costs. Therefore to produce a<br />

robust study that can be generalized, one has to make some delimitation.<br />

Firstly, the study adopted gravity model<strong>in</strong>g to estimate the effects of EAC trade<br />

liberalization. Much as there have been marked improvements <strong>in</strong> its theoretical<br />

5


foundations, there are still disagreements on which type of gravity model to adopt <strong>and</strong><br />

most times they do not fit the dataset quite well. As such, studies have found that the<br />

estimates of the gravity model<strong>in</strong>g are dependent on the covariates used <strong>and</strong> their<br />

number. For this reason, gravity model<strong>in</strong>g has a tendency to either underestimate or<br />

overestimate the weight of the estimates depend<strong>in</strong>g on the choice of covariates.<br />

Secondly, the study uses a panel dataset of bilateral trade spann<strong>in</strong>g 22 years for<br />

185 countries. In us<strong>in</strong>g this type of dataset, there is a problem of attrition when the<br />

EAC member states cease trad<strong>in</strong>g with a partner or vice versa. S<strong>in</strong>ce the problem of<br />

the attrition <strong>in</strong> this data set seems to be completely r<strong>and</strong>om, the adoption of the data<br />

set should not be problematic. However, s<strong>in</strong>ce EAC member states would concentrate<br />

on certa<strong>in</strong> trad<strong>in</strong>g partners, <strong>and</strong> hence dropp<strong>in</strong>g the partners with limited trade<br />

deal<strong>in</strong>gs, the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs could give an impression that trad<strong>in</strong>g relationships are<br />

improv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> profitable for those trad<strong>in</strong>g blocs (countries) than others, <strong>and</strong> further<br />

the concentration of trad<strong>in</strong>g with selective partners (the partners become non-r<strong>and</strong>om)<br />

with a large or significant trad<strong>in</strong>g with them. Besides this, span of the dataset used<br />

was purely <strong>in</strong>fluenced by availability of data for those countries <strong>in</strong> the databases.<br />

Availability of more years would provide more degrees of freedom to do a more<br />

robust analysis.<br />

Thirdly, the study did not focus on <strong>in</strong>ter bloc trade, rather on <strong>in</strong>tra-EAC bloc trade.<br />

This can be conceived from the fact that, it does not <strong>in</strong>clude tariffs <strong>in</strong> its analysis. An<br />

<strong>in</strong>clusion of tariffs is expected to provide more valid estimates. However, tariff<br />

exclusion from the analysis should not negate the results of this study, s<strong>in</strong>ce all the<br />

exporters <strong>in</strong> this study benefit from Special <strong>and</strong> Differential Treatment, <strong>and</strong> therefore<br />

the tariffs should not be expected to have a measurable effect on trade.<br />

1.9 Organization of the Study<br />

This thesis paper h<strong>in</strong>ges upon the above mentioned questions. And the rest of this<br />

paper is structured as follows: In chapter 2, the study provides a background to East<br />

Africa Community. The core of the discussion is centered on the evolution of EAC<br />

<strong>and</strong> attempts at effect<strong>in</strong>g food trade; agriculture <strong>and</strong> food policy provisions of the<br />

protocol establish<strong>in</strong>g the EAC <strong>and</strong> a confabb<strong>in</strong>g adequacy of the protocol to enable<br />

food <strong>and</strong> agricultural production <strong>and</strong> trade; <strong>and</strong> a discussion on the dynamics <strong>and</strong><br />

trends <strong>in</strong> EAC food trade.<br />

In chapter 3, the study selectively reviews empirical <strong>and</strong> theoretical literature on<br />

EAC. It also elaborates on the developments <strong>in</strong> trade policies, <strong>and</strong> elaborates on the<br />

theoretical foundations of the gravity model <strong>and</strong> it strengths <strong>in</strong> estimations. Chapter 4<br />

provides the analytical framework <strong>and</strong> methodology adopted. In chapter 5, the<br />

6


presentation of f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> their discussion was done. And the study is concluded <strong>in</strong><br />

chapter 6 with recommendations <strong>and</strong> provides policy recommendations or<br />

implications of the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs to EAC member states‟ regional trade policy.<br />

7


Chapter Two<br />

2.0 Background to the EAC <strong>and</strong>Food Item<strong>Trade</strong><br />

2.1 Evolution of EAC: From Cooperation to Common<br />

Market <strong>and</strong> Beyond<br />

The current EAC is a realization of years of collaborations <strong>and</strong> cooperation way<br />

before colonialism <strong>in</strong> the second half of the n<strong>in</strong>eteenth century. Cooperation before<br />

the advent of colonialism came to be known as the East African Long distance trade.<br />

The major players were Indians <strong>and</strong> Arabs who travelled us<strong>in</strong>g ships driven by<br />

Monsoon w<strong>in</strong>ds to <strong>and</strong> fro India <strong>and</strong> the Far East, <strong>and</strong> local K<strong>in</strong>gs, Sultans or<br />

powerful persons who controlled trade routes.<br />

The structure <strong>in</strong>volved first <strong>in</strong>tra-regional trade <strong>and</strong> then <strong>in</strong>ter-regional trade<br />

as goods were then moved to the East African coast majorly 2 . The <strong>in</strong>tra-regional trade<br />

structure <strong>in</strong>volved commodities be<strong>in</strong>g traded from a market <strong>in</strong> one village to a market<br />

<strong>in</strong> another village. The goods traded were highly specialized <strong>and</strong> the supply<strong>in</strong>g<br />

village had comparative advantage <strong>in</strong> produc<strong>in</strong>g those goods. This was probably<br />

because they were naturally endowed with the raw materials or producers had unique<br />

skills <strong>in</strong> produc<strong>in</strong>g them 3 .The range of goods traded were; agricultural food items,<br />

pottery, wood carv<strong>in</strong>gs, beads, backcloth, <strong>and</strong> salt among other products.<br />

There was another range of goods that were most dem<strong>and</strong>ed by Europeans,<br />

Indians <strong>and</strong> people from the Far East. This range of products <strong>in</strong>cluded; cloves, slaves,<br />

2 As dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>creased, coastal <strong>and</strong> powerful moved further <strong>in</strong>l<strong>and</strong> to control the whole supply cha<strong>in</strong>.<br />

3 Mode of exchange was largely barter (i.e. exchange of goods for goods or service for service), but <strong>in</strong><br />

some case there were some form currency. With <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the number of transactions, the trade<br />

structure seemed not to be dynamic due to its simplicity.<br />

8


iron ore, m<strong>in</strong>erals like gold, copper, salt <strong>and</strong> spices which were transacted over<br />

greater distances at market po<strong>in</strong>ts close to state boundaries or capitals like Kilwa 4 at<br />

the coast l<strong>in</strong>e of the East African Indian Ocean 5 . To protect or control the trade routes<br />

or villages, one community would subdue another. With time, this was not tenable,<br />

cooperation then became as the modusoper<strong>and</strong>i.<br />

When the British (Colonial Adm<strong>in</strong>istrators) arrived <strong>in</strong> East Africa, they<br />

brought about many changes <strong>in</strong> the supply cha<strong>in</strong>. They firstly abolished trade <strong>in</strong><br />

slaves <strong>and</strong> with time <strong>in</strong>troduced new cropp<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> trad<strong>in</strong>g patterns that served their<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustries <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>terests. Under them, Kenya, Tanzania <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a enjoyed a new<br />

wave of cooperation under successive regional <strong>in</strong>tegration arrangements. All the<br />

arrangements under the colonial period which lasted about 60 years were forced upon<br />

the member states.<br />

Table 2.1 below illustrate the chronology <strong>in</strong> the process of EAC <strong>in</strong>tegration,<br />

from an imposed customs union by the British Colonial Adm<strong>in</strong>istration between<br />

Kenya <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a <strong>in</strong> 1917 to be<strong>in</strong>g the first trad<strong>in</strong>g bloc to liberally sign a common<br />

market protocol <strong>in</strong> the natural-resources-rich-cont<strong>in</strong>ent of Africa with an eye to<br />

bolster trade, <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>and</strong> other economic undertak<strong>in</strong>gs.<br />

Table 2.1: Evolution of East African Common Market Protocol<br />

Era Episode Milestone<br />

Colonial Period<br />

1897- 1901 Commencement of<br />

formal cooperation <strong>in</strong> East<br />

Africa (Kenya&Ug<strong>and</strong>a)<br />

1905 East Africa Currency<br />

Board established<br />

Postal Union established<br />

Construction of Kenya-Ug<strong>and</strong>a railway<br />

(1897-1901)<br />

Establishment of customs collection<br />

center <strong>in</strong> 1900<br />

Monetary Union with a s<strong>in</strong>gle currency<br />

<strong>in</strong> place till 1966; it was responsible for<br />

issu<strong>in</strong>g & redeem<strong>in</strong>g local currency for<br />

Sterl<strong>in</strong>g. EAC belonged to the Sterl<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Exchange System; no restrictions on capital<br />

movements.<br />

1919 Customs Union between Jo<strong>in</strong>t adm<strong>in</strong>ister<strong>in</strong>g of customs, excise<br />

4 The Portuguese are said to have been amazed by the level of organization <strong>and</strong> development of this<br />

coastal city, <strong>and</strong> thought it was more comparable to cities <strong>in</strong> Europe.<br />

5 This is where enterpris<strong>in</strong>g South-Asians cooperated to their mutual advantage <strong>in</strong> economic<br />

development of the whole region (Gregory, R. G 1981).<br />

9


Ug<strong>and</strong>a&Kenya & <strong>in</strong>come tax; <strong>and</strong> other services such as<br />

medical & <strong>in</strong>dustrial researches, education,<br />

transport & communication, <strong>and</strong> agriculture.<br />

1927 Tanzania(formerly<br />

Tanganyika) jo<strong>in</strong>s customs<br />

union<br />

1931 Kenya-Ug<strong>and</strong>a railway<br />

opened<br />

1948 Establishment of the<br />

East African High Commission<br />

(EAHC) till 1961.<br />

1961 East African Common<br />

Services Organization<br />

Independent States6<br />

1961,<br />

1962, 1963<br />

<strong>and</strong> 1964<br />

Agreement (1961 – 1966)<br />

Ma<strong>in</strong>l<strong>and</strong> Tanzania<br />

ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>dependence from the<br />

British <strong>in</strong> 1961. Followed by<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a <strong>in</strong> 1962 <strong>and</strong> Kenya <strong>in</strong><br />

1963. In 1964, Tanzania unifies<br />

with Zanzibar to become one<br />

country.<br />

Common external tariff, jo<strong>in</strong>tly run a<br />

monetary union <strong>and</strong> consolidated fiscal<br />

<strong>in</strong>tegration; <strong>and</strong> mobility of labor allowed.<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a had a direct l<strong>in</strong>k to the Indian<br />

Oceanserviced by the rail.<br />

Inter-territorial co-operation<br />

formalized, common legislative body<br />

(considered & enacted legislation relat<strong>in</strong>g to<br />

aspects of common services) <strong>and</strong><br />

adm<strong>in</strong>istrative organ operated with 3<br />

governors of the territories with Secretariat <strong>in</strong><br />

Nairobi.<br />

Responsible for the development of<br />

major <strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>and</strong> distribut<strong>in</strong>g them<br />

evenly.<br />

Regulate the commercial <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustrial<br />

relations <strong>and</strong> transactions between the said<br />

countries<br />

<strong>and</strong> enacted central legislature on<br />

behalf of the said countries, laws relevant to<br />

the purposes of the said jo<strong>in</strong>t organizations<br />

Many changes effected <strong>in</strong> the<br />

mach<strong>in</strong>ery of cooperation <strong>and</strong> the EAHC was<br />

transformed to East African Common Services<br />

Organization (EASCO) which consisted of<br />

Chief Executive from the 3 countries. The<br />

Central Legislative Assembly (CLA)<br />

<strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong> 1948 was enlarged <strong>and</strong> operated<br />

through committees run by m<strong>in</strong>isters from the<br />

member states.<br />

6 <strong>Integration</strong> which had „colonial‟ arrangement needed to be changed after <strong>in</strong>dependence.<br />

Developments were imposed on states prior to this.<br />

10


1967 Treaty for East Africa<br />

Community enacted & signed<br />

Arusha Declaration by<br />

Tanzania (socialist move)<br />

1970 Common Man‟s Charter<br />

&Nakivubo Pronouncement by<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a<br />

1971<br />

– 1985<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a experiences<br />

Civil unrest <strong>and</strong> political<br />

<strong>in</strong>stability<br />

Operations of all these bodies went on<br />

without any formal enactment of authority.<br />

<br />

Establishment of the EAC <strong>and</strong> The<br />

East African Council with 3 presidents & five<br />

councils assigned for a common market,<br />

communications, economics & plann<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

f<strong>in</strong>ance & research <strong>and</strong> social affairs.<br />

Separate Central banks created but<br />

EAC had harmonized monetary policies to the<br />

extent of proper function<strong>in</strong>g of common<br />

market & aims of community.<br />

Separate currencies which were<br />

identical <strong>and</strong> could be used <strong>in</strong> any territory.<br />

Tanzania nationalizes banks <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>troduces exchange controls to restrict capital<br />

flight to Ug<strong>and</strong>a&Kenya.<br />

Capital outflow from Ug<strong>and</strong>a due to<br />

nationalization; exchange rate controls aga<strong>in</strong>st<br />

Tanzania&Kenya <strong>in</strong>troduced; export & import<br />

of Ug<strong>and</strong>an currency banned.<br />

Exchange rate controls followed<br />

different pegg<strong>in</strong>g of currencies.<br />

Dr. Apollo Milton Obote is deposed<br />

<strong>and</strong> replaced by a dictator.<br />

Differences <strong>in</strong> ideology <strong>and</strong> economic<br />

disparities emerge.<br />

1977 Dissolution of EAC the ma<strong>in</strong> reasons contribut<strong>in</strong>g to the<br />

collapse of the East African Community<br />

be<strong>in</strong>g;<br />

lack of strong political will,<br />

lack of strong participation of the<br />

private sector <strong>and</strong> civil society <strong>in</strong> the cooperation<br />

activities,<br />

the cont<strong>in</strong>ued disproportionate shar<strong>in</strong>g<br />

of benefits of the Community among the<br />

11


1984 East African Mediation<br />

Agreement 1984, on 14th May<br />

1993 Permanent Tripartite<br />

Commission established for<br />

cooperation <strong>in</strong> EA<br />

1999 Treaty establish<strong>in</strong>g<br />

EAC is launched on<br />

30thNovember<br />

2000<br />

<br />

Enter<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to force of<br />

EAC Treaty<br />

2005 Establishment of EAC<br />

Customs Union<br />

Partner States due to their differences <strong>in</strong> their<br />

levels of development<br />

<strong>and</strong> lack of adequate policies to<br />

address this situation;<br />

<br />

Assets <strong>and</strong> liabilities of defunct EAC<br />

were divided among partner states<br />

Provision is made <strong>in</strong> agreement to<br />

enable partners to explore <strong>and</strong> identify areas of<br />

future cooperation.<br />

responsible for the co-ord<strong>in</strong>ation of<br />

economic, social, cultural, security <strong>and</strong><br />

political issues among the said countries<br />

Operations did not commence<br />

immediately till 1996 when secretariat was<br />

launched.<br />

Agreement went for parliamentary &<br />

public scrut<strong>in</strong>y before updat<strong>in</strong>g to treaty.<br />

EAC had several <strong>in</strong>stitutions to ensure<br />

its objective; The Summit, The Co-ord<strong>in</strong>ation<br />

Committee, Sectoral Committee, EAC Court,<br />

EAC Assembly <strong>and</strong> the Secretariat<br />

On 7th July follow<strong>in</strong>g ratification of<br />

the 3 orig<strong>in</strong>al members.<br />

Objective is to form a s<strong>in</strong>gle customs<br />

territory<br />

Introduction of Common External<br />

Tariff (CET)<br />

2007 Enlargement of EAC Rw<strong>and</strong>a&Burundi acceded EAC on<br />

18th June <strong>and</strong> become full member on 1st July<br />

same year<br />

2009 Common Market<br />

Protocol<br />

allows free movement of people,<br />

goods, labor <strong>and</strong> capital across the member<br />

countries<br />

came <strong>in</strong>to effect <strong>in</strong> July 2010<br />

2011 EAC Food Security Increase food item trade between the<br />

12


Action Plan (2011 – 2015) deficit <strong>and</strong> surplus areas or countries<br />

2012 Monetary Union <br />

2014 Political Federation <br />

Table 1 above summarizes the progression of cooperation <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment, commerce,<br />

economic <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry enjoyed by the East African member states after the arrival of<br />

colonialism to date. The former East African community was set up <strong>in</strong> 1967 <strong>and</strong><br />

collapsed <strong>in</strong> 1977. In 1999, the heads of states signed an agreement, follow<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

spirit of previous cooperation to set up a „New‟ East African Community which came<br />

<strong>in</strong>to force <strong>in</strong> 2000. S<strong>in</strong>ce then, it has exp<strong>and</strong>ed from three member countries to five <strong>in</strong><br />

2007 with the jo<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g of Rw<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Burundi. The Democratic Republic of Congo<br />

(DRC) <strong>and</strong> Sudan have also <strong>in</strong>dicated <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> jo<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the bloc. Many academicians<br />

are also foresee<strong>in</strong>g Ethiopia breed<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> the group. However, the newly<br />

formed Southern Sudan state may become the next country to jo<strong>in</strong> EAC before any<br />

other country.<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ce the revival of the East African Community, the follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

accomplishments have been experienced <strong>in</strong> the area of trade;<br />

a. Ongo<strong>in</strong>g implementation of tariff reduction with Kenya, Ug<strong>and</strong>a & Tanzania<br />

apply<strong>in</strong>g 90 percent <strong>and</strong> 80 reduction respectively, removal of all cross border nontariff<br />

barriers;<br />

b. Ongo<strong>in</strong>g harmonization of capital markets policies, trad<strong>in</strong>g practices <strong>and</strong><br />

regulation <strong>in</strong> the stock exchanges of the member countries under the auspice of East<br />

African Securities Regulatory Authorities (EASRA);<br />

c. Harmonization of fiscal <strong>and</strong> monetary policies aim<strong>in</strong>g at harmoniz<strong>in</strong>g;<br />

bank<strong>in</strong>g rules, VAT rates, pre-shipment requirements; <strong>and</strong> movement towards<br />

mak<strong>in</strong>g partner states currencies convertible, macroeconomic framework <strong>and</strong><br />

avoidance of double taxation; <strong>and</strong><br />

d. Formation of a customs union <strong>and</strong> common market protocol.<br />

These developments show the deepen<strong>in</strong>g of trade among member states. However,<br />

there seems not have been an explicit policy on food item trade or even agricultural<br />

trade until 2009 when the EAC Common Market protocol came <strong>in</strong> place <strong>and</strong> an<br />

action plan for the implementation of chapter 105 – 110 developed <strong>in</strong> 2011. Even<br />

then the policies on food item trade <strong>in</strong> particular <strong>and</strong> agriculture <strong>in</strong> general is still not<br />

well conceived. The programs are ambitious <strong>and</strong> need clear synchronization with<br />

other programs like program on <strong>in</strong>frastructure, climate change, <strong>and</strong> poverty<br />

13


eradication among other <strong>in</strong>tentions. Important to note, that food item trade is<br />

conceived under the auspices of improv<strong>in</strong>g food security.<br />

2.2 EAC Food <strong>and</strong> Agricultural Program<br />

In order to underst<strong>and</strong> the EAC food item program, one must look at the treaty or<br />

protocol that formed the EAC <strong>in</strong> 1999. This is the protocol that first clearly spelt-out<br />

food <strong>and</strong> agricultural trade <strong>and</strong> development <strong>in</strong> the region, unlike previous<br />

agreements of cooperation. However, much as desire to enhance agriculture <strong>and</strong> food<br />

item production <strong>and</strong> trade is spelt out clearly <strong>in</strong> this protocol, the programs <strong>and</strong><br />

policies to achieve the desires are not well spelt out <strong>and</strong> are amambojumbo of l<strong>in</strong>ked<br />

<strong>and</strong> pegged to all other major programs <strong>and</strong> sectors. Mirrored to the multilateral<br />

agreement AoA, it is clear that the EAC chapters on Agriculture <strong>and</strong> food security<br />

<strong>and</strong> discipl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>and</strong> commitments are way below st<strong>and</strong>ard <strong>and</strong> the program has not<br />

domesticated those discipl<strong>in</strong>es.<br />

2.2.1 Prom<strong>in</strong>ence of Food <strong>and</strong> Agriculture <strong>in</strong> EAC Common Market<br />

Protocol.<br />

In the implementation of the EAC Common Market Protocol, the facilitation of the<br />

trade <strong>in</strong> food commodities <strong>and</strong> products has been given first priority. This is deemed<br />

to ensure food security, when food surplus areas or countries transfer the surplus to<br />

food deficit productions po<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> EAC. Also, s<strong>in</strong>ce the ma<strong>in</strong> occupation of EAC<br />

citizen is <strong>in</strong> the production of food commodities, <strong>in</strong>creased trade <strong>in</strong> food products is<br />

considered to enhance employment <strong>and</strong> the best move to poverty eradication. And<br />

agriculture is the most important sector <strong>and</strong> key area of cooperation <strong>in</strong> the bloc 7 . It<br />

accounts for 36 percent of the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) with lots of untapped<br />

potential, specifically <strong>in</strong> commercial farm<strong>in</strong>g. And eighty percent of the populations<br />

of the community live <strong>in</strong> rural areas depend<strong>in</strong>g on agriculture for their livelihood 8 .<br />

To enhance the ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> EAC trade liberalization, member states have even<br />

elim<strong>in</strong>ated export bans on food commodities <strong>and</strong> products <strong>in</strong>tended for consumption<br />

<strong>in</strong> the region. The states have also had an ongo<strong>in</strong>g process of improv<strong>in</strong>g the transport<br />

<strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>and</strong> with priority on highways <strong>and</strong> railways on the one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

development of the feeder roads to enable the optimal utilization of the transport<br />

7 Source is EAC„s Agenda for Agriculture. And it accounts for about 44 percent of GDP <strong>in</strong> Burundi<br />

<strong>and</strong> Tanzania, 30 percent <strong>in</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a, 24 percent <strong>in</strong> Kenya <strong>and</strong> 38 percent <strong>in</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a (2006 figures).<br />

8 ibid<br />

14


<strong>in</strong>frastructure. They are engaged <strong>in</strong> the development of the food market-support<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>frastructure, to reduce the transaction cost of this trade.<br />

2.2.2 Treatment of Agriculture <strong>in</strong> the EAC Common Protocol (Article<br />

105 – 110)<br />

Article 105 – 110 of the Treaty Establish<strong>in</strong>g the EAC <strong>and</strong> specifically Chapter 18,<br />

outl<strong>in</strong>es the key area of cooperation of Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Food security. And the most<br />

prom<strong>in</strong>ent objective of agricultural cooperation <strong>in</strong> EAC is the achievement of food<br />

security <strong>and</strong> rational agricultural production.<br />

In order to rationalize agricultural production with a view to promote<br />

complimentary <strong>and</strong> specialization <strong>and</strong> susta<strong>in</strong>ability of national agricultural<br />

programs, partner states have adopted the follow<strong>in</strong>g objectives;<br />

a common agricultural policy;<br />

food sufficiency with<strong>in</strong> the Community;<br />

an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the production of crops, livestock, fisheries <strong>and</strong> forest products for<br />

domestic consumption, exports with<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> outside the Community <strong>and</strong> as <strong>in</strong>puts<br />

to agro-based <strong>in</strong>dustries with<strong>in</strong> the Community; <strong>and</strong><br />

post-harvest preservation <strong>and</strong> conservation <strong>and</strong> improved food process<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

For purposes of paragraph 1 of Article 105, the Partner States undertake to co-operate<br />

<strong>in</strong> specific fields of agriculture, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g:<br />

the harmonization of agricultural policies of the Partner States;<br />

the development of food security with<strong>in</strong> the partner states <strong>and</strong> the Community as<br />

a whole, through the production <strong>and</strong> supply of foodstuffs;<br />

agro-meteorology <strong>and</strong> climatology to promote the development of early<br />

climatological warn<strong>in</strong>g systems with<strong>in</strong> the Community;<br />

the development <strong>and</strong> application of agricultural tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> research <strong>and</strong><br />

extension services;<br />

the adoption of <strong>in</strong>ternationally accepted quality st<strong>and</strong>ards for food process<strong>in</strong>g;<br />

the establishment of jo<strong>in</strong>t programs for the control of animal <strong>and</strong> plant diseases<br />

<strong>and</strong> pests;<br />

the market<strong>in</strong>g of food <strong>and</strong> the co-ord<strong>in</strong>ation of the export <strong>and</strong> import of<br />

agricultural commodities;<br />

jo<strong>in</strong>t actions <strong>in</strong> combat<strong>in</strong>g drought <strong>and</strong> desertification ; <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong> such other fields of agriculture as the Council may determ<strong>in</strong>e.<br />

15


The EAC Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural Development Policy (EAC – ARDP) was developed<br />

as an <strong>in</strong>itial step towards the implementation of the provisions of the treaty. It reflects<br />

the commitment of the partner States to foster their economic co-operation for the<br />

benefit of their people.<br />

2.3 Inter - Sectoral Trends <strong>and</strong> Structure of the Selected<br />

Exports of the EAC<br />

In this section, the statistics on the composition of EAC exports of the selected<br />

products is presented <strong>in</strong> section 2.3.1. Section 2.3.2, makes a discussion <strong>and</strong><br />

presentation of the trends <strong>and</strong> discussion of the contribution of EAC exports by<br />

member states. In section 2.3.3, the paper takes on a discussion of the exports of the<br />

<strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports.<br />

2.3.1 EAC Export Trends <strong>and</strong> its Constitution by Product.<br />

Figure 2.1 below shows the trend <strong>in</strong> EAC exports <strong>and</strong> its constitution by the selected<br />

products. There has been a persistent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the volume of exports of the selected<br />

products s<strong>in</strong>ce 1988. However, s<strong>in</strong>ce the formation of the EAC <strong>in</strong> 2000, the upward<br />

trend <strong>in</strong> the graph seems to have picked up. This upward sw<strong>in</strong>g was even more<br />

significant around 2005 when EAC became a customs union <strong>and</strong> even surged further<br />

skyward, when Burundi <strong>and</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a formally jo<strong>in</strong>ed the bloc, until it picked up to<br />

over 20 percent of the value of total exports <strong>in</strong> 2008.<br />

16


Figure 2.1 Exports Growth <strong>and</strong> Composition of the Selected EAC <strong>Products</strong><br />

2.3.2 EAC Member States Contribution to Export of the Selected<br />

<strong>Products</strong><br />

All the EAC member states‟ exports, they seem to follow a similar trend like the bloc<br />

exports of the selected product or sector categories. However, Kenya‟s exports seem<br />

to s<strong>in</strong>gly expla<strong>in</strong> the bloc exports. For each year, Kenya‟s export is almost more than<br />

double the comb<strong>in</strong>ed exports value of all the other states. Rw<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Burundi<br />

exports contribute about one million dollars. Tanzania‟s exports are the second<br />

largest exports <strong>in</strong> the region, followed by Ug<strong>and</strong>a. Tanzania‟s exports surpassed the 1<br />

billion dollar mark around the year 2003, while Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s exports surpassed this mark<br />

just two years ago. However, Tanzania‟s exports have not yet surpassed the 3 billion<br />

dollar mark. Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s exports are still below the 2 billion dollar mark. However,<br />

Kenya‟s exports have reached the 6 billion dollar mark <strong>and</strong> have been more than 3<br />

billion dollars mark s<strong>in</strong>ce 2004. See figure 2.2 below for clarity on the above<br />

conclusions.<br />

17


Figure 2.2 Relative Contributions of EAC Member States to the <strong>Trade</strong> of Selected<br />

<strong>Products</strong><br />

2.3.3 Country Decomposition of EAC Exports by Sector<br />

In figure 2.3 below, a stacked panel (A, B, C, D <strong>and</strong> E) of graphs show<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

decomposition of EAC states exports by sector is shown. Panel A, B, C, D <strong>and</strong> E<br />

respectively show the decomposition of food item trade, agricultural raw materials<br />

(AgriRaw), fuels, Ores <strong>and</strong> Metals (OresMtls) <strong>and</strong> Manufactures (Manuf) exports of<br />

EAC <strong>in</strong> millions (MM) of US dollars (USD). Overall, the trend <strong>in</strong> exports for all<br />

products has experienced a significant surge when the EAC was formed.<br />

The value of EAC members‟ food Item trade is shown <strong>in</strong> figure 2.3.1 <strong>in</strong> panel<br />

A below. From the figure, Burundi <strong>and</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a hardly export any food items. The<br />

comb<strong>in</strong>ed value of their food item exports is still below 100 millions of US dollars.<br />

Kenya is the major exporter by value of food items from the bloc. Kenya‟s exports<br />

have persistently grown from over 500 million US dollars at the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the<br />

period to about 2000 million of US dollars at the end of the period. Ug<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong><br />

Tanzania‟s export values of food items have relatively grown at the same rate.<br />

However, Tanzania‟s <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s value of food exports have only surpassed the<br />

18


500 million US dollar mark <strong>in</strong> 2004 <strong>and</strong> 2005 respectively. And they are about to<br />

clock the 1000 million US dollar mark at the end of the period under consideration.<br />

Figure 2.3.2 <strong>in</strong> Panel B, shows the value of agricultural raw materials exports<br />

of EAC. From the figure, Kenya <strong>and</strong> Tanzania are the major exporters by value of the<br />

agricultural raw materials. At the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the period, Kenya was export<strong>in</strong>g about<br />

200 million US dollars of agricultural raw materials. By 2000, the value surpassed the<br />

500 million value of export of agricultural raw materials, <strong>and</strong> peaked 1700 millions of<br />

US dollars at the end of the period under consideration. Tanzania‟ exports were<br />

grow<strong>in</strong>g at the same rate with Kenya‟s until the mid-1990s when Kenya‟s export<br />

value of agricultural raw materials surpassed its exports of the same product.<br />

Tanzania‟ exports only surpassed the 500 million US dollar mark around 2004 but<br />

have not yet reached the 1000 million US dollar mark. The comb<strong>in</strong>ed value of<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a, Rw<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Burundi‟s agricultural raw materials not yet more than 500<br />

million US dollars.<br />

In Panel C, figure 2.3.3 is show<strong>in</strong>g the value of the exports of fuel trade from<br />

EAC. Kenya <strong>and</strong> Tanzania are still the major countries export<strong>in</strong>g this product too.<br />

Kenya‟s exports for fuel have grown from zero exports <strong>in</strong> 1988 to peak over 350<br />

million US dollars <strong>in</strong> 2005. From then, it experienced a significant drop but still<br />

above 150 million US dollars, though it has picked up now. Much as Tanzania is on<br />

average the second major export of fuels, its exports have never gone beyond 150<br />

million US dollars. Rw<strong>and</strong>a experienced a surge <strong>in</strong> exports between 2001 <strong>and</strong> 2005.<br />

Its exports of fuels peaked about 270 million US dollars dur<strong>in</strong>g this time. This is the<br />

only time Rw<strong>and</strong>a seemed to export fuel. Ug<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Burundi hardly export any fuel.<br />

The exports of ores <strong>and</strong> metals are shown <strong>in</strong> figure 3.3.4 <strong>in</strong> Panel D. Between<br />

1988 <strong>and</strong> before the promulgation of the EAC <strong>in</strong> 2000, the value of exports for ores<br />

<strong>and</strong> metals was <strong>in</strong>significant. On average, the value of the exports of ores <strong>and</strong> metals<br />

was less than 50 million US dollars for all the countries dur<strong>in</strong>g this period. From<br />

2000, the exports of fuels seemed to have picked up for all countries except Burundi.<br />

This trend picked up further after 2005 when EAC became a Customs Union.<br />

However, Tanzania is the major export of ores <strong>and</strong> metals, followed by Kenya,<br />

Rw<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong> then Ug<strong>and</strong>a. Tanzania‟s exports peaked an export value of about 290<br />

million US dollars <strong>in</strong> 2007. Kenya is yet to reach 200 million UD dollars of export of<br />

ores <strong>and</strong> metals, Rw<strong>and</strong>a just clocked the 200 million US dollars mark <strong>in</strong> 2007, <strong>and</strong><br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a just clocked 50 million US dollars <strong>in</strong> the same year.<br />

Figure 2.3.5 <strong>in</strong> Panel E shows the decomposition of manufactured item trade<br />

by country. Rw<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Burundi hardly export any food products. They comb<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

exports of manufactured items have been less than 100 million US dollars. Kenya<br />

19


exports the most manufactured item from the region <strong>and</strong> exports have persistently<br />

grown from less than 100 US dollars <strong>in</strong> 1988 to over 2000 million US dollars <strong>in</strong><br />

2008. Kenyan surpassed the 500 million US dollars value of manufactured exports<br />

around 1994. Tanzania is the second major exporter of manufactured items from the<br />

region. Much as the country‟s exports have a persistent growth, the only surpassed<br />

the 500 million US dollar value of exports <strong>in</strong> 2007. Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s exports of<br />

manufactured items are still low <strong>and</strong> it has not yet surpassed the 500 million US<br />

dollar mark. However, s<strong>in</strong>ce 2006, the exports have picked up almost clock<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

500 million US dollar mark.<br />

20


Figure 2.3 Show<strong>in</strong>g EAC Sector‟s Stacked Graphs Decomposed by Country<br />

Panel A: Figure 2.3.1 Show<strong>in</strong>g Country Decomposition of Food<br />

Exports<br />

Panel C: Figure 2.3.3 Show<strong>in</strong>g Country Decomposition of Fuels<br />

Exports<br />

Panel E: Figure 2.3.5 Show<strong>in</strong>g Country Decomposition of Manuf<br />

Exports<br />

Panel B: Figure 2.3.2 Show<strong>in</strong>g Country Decomposition of AgriRaw<br />

Exports<br />

Panel D: Figure 2.3.4 Show<strong>in</strong>g Country Decomposition of OresMtls<br />

Exports<br />

21


2.3.4 Sectoral Decomposition of EAC Exports by Country<br />

In figure 2.4 below, a stacked panel (a, b, c, d <strong>and</strong> e) of figures show<strong>in</strong>g the composition of each<br />

EAC member states‟ percentage composition of their exports is shown. Overall, the percentage<br />

of food item exports is more than any other commodity. On average, food item exports constitute<br />

more than 50 percent of the total exports. Burundi, Kenya <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a have more than an<br />

average of 80 percent of their exports constitut<strong>in</strong>g food item over the period. For all countries,<br />

their exports of food item seemed to have reduced, but still above 50 percent of exports, between<br />

2003 <strong>and</strong> 2007. After this period, the food exports seem to pick up. However, Rw<strong>and</strong>a‟s food<br />

export seemed to experience the most drastic reduction to about 40 percent of its total exports.<br />

Burundi that jo<strong>in</strong>ed EAC <strong>in</strong> 2007 has food item trade <strong>and</strong> manufactured goods as it major<br />

exports. Food items are on averaged contribut<strong>in</strong>g over 75 percent of Burundi‟s total export value.<br />

However, it had a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> exports from its highest values of 85 percent <strong>in</strong> 1998 to its lowest<br />

value of 45 percent <strong>in</strong> 2002. However, s<strong>in</strong>ce 2006 when it had another low, Rw<strong>and</strong>a‟s food item<br />

trade has picked up. Dur<strong>in</strong>g this very period, the composition of manufactured goods as a<br />

composition of total export value of the selected products has <strong>in</strong>creased to the magnitude of the<br />

shortfall <strong>in</strong> food item trade. Burundi‟s exports of agricultural raw materials follows <strong>in</strong><br />

importance <strong>in</strong> the composition of total export value. It contributed on average 5 percent dur<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the period under consideration. However, s<strong>in</strong>ce 2006, the percentage contribution of raw<br />

materials has picked up. Burundi hardly exports fuels. Its exports of ores <strong>and</strong> metals are less than<br />

three percent over the period under consideration.<br />

Panel B shows the contribution of Kenya. From the figure, the exports of Kenya are<br />

concentrated to food items, manufactured goods <strong>and</strong> agricultural raw materials. The percentage<br />

of food item exports is the strongest among these. However, it has been persistently decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

from 65 percent highest contribution <strong>in</strong> 1998 to its lowest of about 30 percent between 2006 <strong>and</strong><br />

2007. It has picked up s<strong>in</strong>ce then but still below 40 percent. The contribution of fuels <strong>and</strong><br />

manufactured goods <strong>in</strong> Kenya‟s exports have been pick<strong>in</strong>g up from 20 percent before 1990 to a<br />

current level of about 30 percent. Ores <strong>and</strong> metals contribute the least to Kenya‟s total export<br />

value of the selected products. The exports of fuels have rema<strong>in</strong>ed lower than 3 percent dur<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the period under consideration.<br />

In panel C, the export dynamics of Rw<strong>and</strong>a‟s trade are presented. Food item trade too, is<br />

the largest contributor to Rw<strong>and</strong>a‟s export trade value of the selected products. On average, it<br />

contributes more than 40 percent to Rw<strong>and</strong>a‟s total exports. However, it suffered drastic surges<br />

to its lowest of 10 percent <strong>in</strong> 2004 form it highest contribution of 85 percent <strong>in</strong> 1996. S<strong>in</strong>ce then,<br />

it has picked up on its average contribution to about 30 percent of total trade. Dur<strong>in</strong>g this time,<br />

fuel exports picked up <strong>and</strong> contributed to a high of 70 percent <strong>in</strong> 2004. However, the period 2001<br />

to 2004, is the only time fuel export contributed significantly to Rw<strong>and</strong>a‟s exports. The second<br />

23


most contributors are agriculture raw materials, which contributed on average 10 percent.<br />

However, s<strong>in</strong>ce 2006 its contribution has grown to 35 percent at the end of the period considered.<br />

Ores <strong>and</strong> metals also play an important role <strong>and</strong> its role is becom<strong>in</strong>g as significant to exports as<br />

agricultural raw materials. The manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector <strong>in</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a is still weak but has persistently<br />

<strong>in</strong>creased on average but still less than 3 percent.<br />

In Tanzania, food, agricultural raw materials <strong>and</strong> manufactures are at the top of exports of<br />

the country. On average, these exports have contributed more than 90 percent of the total value<br />

exports dur<strong>in</strong>g the period. However, food constitutes the most, with an average contribution of<br />

45 percent dur<strong>in</strong>g the period. Exports of all the products are grow<strong>in</strong>g except for food item trade<br />

that has stagnated to an average of 40 percent. Tanzania hardly exports fuels.<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a export dynamics shown <strong>in</strong> panel C <strong>in</strong>dicates that food item trade dom<strong>in</strong>ates it<br />

exports. On average, it contributes over 75 percent. The exports of agricultural raw materials are<br />

also strong, contribut<strong>in</strong>g on the average 15 percent, though from 2007, its role is dim<strong>in</strong>ish<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

The role of manufactures seems to have picked up to 20 percent at the end of the period<br />

considered. The contribution of fuel to Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s exports is <strong>in</strong>significant throughout the period.<br />

24


Figure 2.4 Show<strong>in</strong>g Stacked Graphs of EAC Export Composition for the Selected <strong>Products</strong> by Country<br />

Panel A: Figure 2.4.1Percentage Distribution of Burundi’s Export of<br />

the Selected <strong>Products</strong>.<br />

Panel C: Figure 2.4.3Percentage Distribution of Rw<strong>and</strong>a’s Export of<br />

the Selected <strong>Products</strong><br />

Panel D: Figure 2.4.5 Percentage Distribution of Ug<strong>and</strong>a’s Export of<br />

the Selected <strong>Products</strong><br />

Panel B: Figure 2.4.2Percentage Distribution of Kenya’s<br />

Export of the Selected <strong>Products</strong>.<br />

Panel D: Figure 2.4.4Percentage Distribution of Tanzania’s<br />

Export of the Selected <strong>Products</strong><br />

25


2.4 Intra – Sectoral Trends <strong>and</strong> Structure of the Selected<br />

Exports of the EAC<br />

In this section, the statistics on the composition of <strong>in</strong>tra-EAC exports of the selected products is<br />

presented <strong>in</strong> section 2.4.1. Section 2.4.2, makes a discussion <strong>and</strong> presentation of the trends <strong>and</strong><br />

discussion of the contribution of EAC exports by member states. In section 2.4.3, the paper takes<br />

on a discussion of the exports of the <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports.<br />

The effect of EAC formation seems to filter through the <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports of all the<br />

products for all the countries. This is because, there seem to be a surge <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports for<br />

all countries dur<strong>in</strong>g the period when there are deepen<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>in</strong>tegration, around 2005 or 2007.<br />

However, it can be deduced that, the effect of the crisis seem to dampen these achievements.<br />

2.4.1 Intra - EAC Export Trends <strong>and</strong> its Constitution by Product.<br />

Figure 2.5 below shows the trend <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>tra-EAC exports <strong>and</strong> its constitution by the selected<br />

products. There has been a persistent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the volume of exports of the selected products<br />

s<strong>in</strong>ce 1990. The trend surge upward with the formation of the EAC <strong>in</strong> 2000, strengthen<strong>in</strong>g even<br />

more, after the transformation of the bloc to a customs union <strong>in</strong> 2005. However, this trend<br />

persisted further upward with <strong>in</strong> 2007 when Rw<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Burundi jo<strong>in</strong>ed the bloc. Bloc exports<br />

have moved from less than 100 million US dollars <strong>in</strong> 1990 to a peak of about 2300 million US<br />

dollars at the end of the period under consideration.<br />

The major export product that seems to <strong>in</strong>fluence this trend is the <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports of<br />

manufactured goods. The <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports <strong>in</strong> the rest of the products hardly expla<strong>in</strong> bloc<br />

exports. Their comb<strong>in</strong>ed average exports is only 500 million of US dollars compared to trade <strong>in</strong><br />

manufactured goods which has an average trade of about 1000 millions of US dollars. S<strong>in</strong>ce<br />

2007, the <strong>in</strong>tra bloc exports of food have picked up <strong>and</strong> it is now the second major exports of the<br />

26


loc. However, its <strong>in</strong>tra – bloc exports is still less than 500 million US dollars. The other sector‟s<br />

exports have even dampened further.<br />

Figure 2.6 Exports Growth <strong>and</strong> Composition of the Selected EAC <strong>Products</strong><br />

2.4.2 Intra-EAC Member States Contribution to Export of the Selected <strong>Products</strong><br />

Kenya‟s exports s<strong>in</strong>gly dom<strong>in</strong>ate the <strong>in</strong>tra bloc exports of EAC. Kenya‟s exports have grown<br />

from less than 25 million US dollars <strong>in</strong> 1993 to a peak of over 1500 million US dollars <strong>in</strong> 2008.<br />

The comb<strong>in</strong>ed exports of the rest of the states <strong>in</strong> EAC are less than 700 million US dollars.<br />

However, s<strong>in</strong>ce the formation of EAC, the exports of Ug<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Tanzania have picked up.<br />

Surg<strong>in</strong>g further after EAC became a customs union <strong>in</strong> 2005, but still less than 400 million US<br />

dollars.<br />

Figure 2.7 Relative Contributions of EAC Member States to the <strong>Trade</strong> of Selected <strong>Products</strong><br />

27


2.4.3 Country Decomposition of EAC Exports by Sector<br />

In figure 2.7 below, a stacked panel of graphs show<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc country decomposition of the<br />

value of each export<strong>in</strong>g sector‟s trends is shown. The export dynamics of food, agricultural raw<br />

materials, fuels, ores <strong>and</strong> metals, <strong>and</strong> manufactured goods is shown <strong>in</strong> panel A, B, C, D <strong>and</strong> E<br />

respectively. The effect of EAC formation seems to filter through the <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports of all the<br />

products for all the countries. This is because, there seem to be a surge it <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports for<br />

all countries dur<strong>in</strong>g the period when there are deepen<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>in</strong>tegration around 2005 or 2007.<br />

However, it can be deduced that, the effect of the crisis seem to dampen these achievements.<br />

Panel A below, has figure 2.7.1 show<strong>in</strong>g the each country‟s <strong>in</strong>tra bloc trade <strong>in</strong> food<br />

exports. By far, Kenya, Ug<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Tanzania are the major countries export<strong>in</strong>g food items <strong>in</strong> the<br />

bloc. Burundi <strong>and</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a are <strong>in</strong>significant bloc exporters of food items. Kenya‟s food exports<br />

have grown from less than 10 million US dollars <strong>in</strong> 1993 to around 60 million US dollars around<br />

1998 when it slumped to 30 million US dollars between 2000 <strong>and</strong> 2002. From then on, it<br />

drastically picked up peak<strong>in</strong>g to about 140 million dollars <strong>in</strong> 2008. The food exports of Ug<strong>and</strong>a,<br />

the second major <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc export of the product after Kenya, gradually picked up from less than<br />

10 million US dollars to a peak of about 140 million US dollars <strong>in</strong> 2007. Tanzania‟s <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc<br />

exports followed a similar pattern like that of Ug<strong>and</strong>a, but just picked up after 2005 though it has<br />

not exceeded 60 million UD dollars. From 2008, the food exports seem to shr<strong>in</strong>k for all<br />

countries. From other panels, <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports of agricultural raw materials <strong>and</strong> ores <strong>and</strong><br />

metals, seem to be less than the trade <strong>in</strong> food products for all countries. It is only the <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc<br />

exports of manufactures <strong>and</strong> fuels that outstrip exports of food by value.<br />

Intra-bloc exports of agricultural raw materials are shown <strong>in</strong> figure 2.7.2 <strong>in</strong> Panel B. On<br />

average, Kenya exports the most of this product, followed by Tanzania <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a. The average<br />

28


<strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports of Kenya, Tanzania <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a is about 30, 20 <strong>and</strong> 10 millions of US dollars<br />

for the period under consideration respectively. The comb<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports of Rw<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong><br />

Burundi is less than 5 million of US dollars. All the countries‟ <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports of agricultural<br />

raw materials seem to pick-up after 2007 though the effect of the crisis seems to dampen this<br />

achievement.<br />

Kenya is the only significant exporter of fuels <strong>in</strong> the bloc. The comb<strong>in</strong>ed value of the<br />

<strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports of all other EAC members is on average less than 5 million US dollars.<br />

Kenyan on average exports more than 200 million US dollars over the period. Its <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc<br />

exports peaked a value of 370 million US dollars 2004/2005. For a visual impression of these<br />

deductions, see figure 2.7.3 <strong>in</strong> Panel C of figure 2.7 below.<br />

In figure 2.7.4 of Panel D below, the <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports of ores <strong>and</strong> metals is depicted. A<br />

similar trend of exports as that of fuels is also observed. Kenya is the s<strong>in</strong>gle major exporter of<br />

the product‟s sector <strong>in</strong> the bloc. On average, Kenya has exported ores <strong>and</strong> metals with<strong>in</strong> the bloc<br />

to a tune of about 50 million dollars throughout the period under consideration. However, it had<br />

a peak export value of 90 million US dollars <strong>in</strong> 2008. And the comb<strong>in</strong>ed exports of ores <strong>and</strong><br />

metals are less than 10 million of US dollars over the period.<br />

A similar export pattern is also observed with the exports of manufactured items shown<br />

<strong>in</strong> figure 2.7.5 <strong>in</strong> Panel C. In this figure, it is clear that Kenya is the s<strong>in</strong>gle player of the <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc<br />

exports of manufactured items. On average, it exports about 500 million US dollars of the values<br />

of this product <strong>in</strong> the bloc. This value is far beyond the <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc export value of food items.<br />

From 2005, Ug<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Tanzania‟s exports of manufactures have picked up <strong>and</strong> have both<br />

clocked the 200 million US dollar value. Burundi <strong>and</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a are still <strong>in</strong>significant exporters of<br />

the product <strong>in</strong> the block.<br />

29


Figure 2.7 Show<strong>in</strong>g Stacked Graphs of Intra EAC Bloc Sector Decomposition of Selected <strong>Products</strong>, by Country<br />

Panel A: Figure 2.7.1 Show<strong>in</strong>g Intra-Bloc Exports of Food Panel B: Figure 2.7.2 Show<strong>in</strong>g Intra-Bloc Exports of AgricRaw<br />

Panel A: Figure 2.7.3 Show<strong>in</strong>g Intra-Bloc Exports of Fuel Panel A: Figure 2.7.4 Show<strong>in</strong>g Intra-Bloc Export of OresMtls<br />

Panel A: Figure 2.7.5 Show<strong>in</strong>g Intra-Bloc Exports of Manuf<br />

30


2.4.4 Sectoral Decomposition of Intra - EAC Exports by Country<br />

In figure 2.8 below, a stacked panel (a, b, c, d <strong>and</strong> e) of figures show<strong>in</strong>g the sectoral composition<br />

of each EAC states‟ exports of the selected sectors is shown. Overall, the value of exports from<br />

Kenya seems to dom<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports. This is follow by the average value of Tanzania‟s<br />

<strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s exports <strong>in</strong> the region. Burundi <strong>and</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a‟s exports are on average less than 10<br />

million of US dollars.Further, for all countries, their exports of the selected products seem to<br />

surge upward after 2007 when the exp<strong>and</strong>ed to <strong>in</strong>clude Burundi <strong>and</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a.<br />

Burundi‟s export decomposition of the selected products is shown <strong>in</strong> figure 2.8.1 <strong>in</strong> Panel<br />

A. On average, Burundi exports manufactured goods mostly to the region. On average, it exports<br />

more than 3 million US dollars manufactured goods <strong>in</strong> the region. The comb<strong>in</strong>ed average exports<br />

of the other products from Rw<strong>and</strong>a to the region are less than 3 million US dollars. Except for<br />

fuels whose exports from Rw<strong>and</strong>a reduced significantly after it jo<strong>in</strong>ed the EAC <strong>in</strong> 2007, all the<br />

other products seem to show a resilience to pick up.<br />

Figure 2.8.2 <strong>in</strong> Panel B shows Kenya‟s exports <strong>in</strong> the region. One can deduce that, Kenya<br />

is a major <strong>and</strong> significant exporter of arguably all the products <strong>in</strong> the region. However, its major<br />

export is manufactured products followed by fuels. Its exports of manufacture have been<br />

grow<strong>in</strong>g gradually from less than 10 million US dollars <strong>in</strong> 1993 to a peak of over 1000 million<br />

US dollars at the end of the period under consideration. On average, the exports of fuels are<br />

slightly below 200 million US dollars over the period. The rest of the products have an average<br />

comb<strong>in</strong>ed export value of less than 100 million US dollars. The export value of Kenya‟s export<br />

seems to dampen at the end of the period. This is probably due to the effect of the f<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

crisis.<br />

Rw<strong>and</strong>a does not seem to have a major dom<strong>in</strong>ant export product. The total value of it<br />

exports is less than 10 million US dollars over the period. Apart from food exports, all the other<br />

products seem to pick up <strong>in</strong> terms of export value at the end of the period. These deductions can<br />

be elaborate upon <strong>in</strong> figure 2.8.3 <strong>in</strong> Panel C below.<br />

For Tanzania, the comb<strong>in</strong>ed value of exports was less than 100 million US dollars for 10<br />

years from 1990. From then on, Tanzania‟s exports of manufactures significantly picked up from<br />

less than 25 million US dollars to a peak of 200 million US dollars at the end of the period. Food<br />

exports also picked up but it value is still less than 70 million US dollars. Agricultural raw<br />

materials are Tanzania‟s third major export of the selected products. However, its average value<br />

of <strong>in</strong>tra bloc exports is still less than 50 million US dollars for this period. The rest of the<br />

products, ores <strong>and</strong> metals <strong>and</strong> fuels, have an average <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc export value of less than 25<br />

million US dollars for the whole period under consideration. To clarify on this, see figure 2.8.4<br />

<strong>in</strong> Panel D below.<br />

31


Figure 2.8.5 <strong>in</strong> Panel C below, shows Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports. From the figure, Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s<br />

exports follow a similar trend as that of Tanzania. Food exports are Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s second major<br />

export <strong>in</strong> the bloc. Its average export value is more than 80 million US dollars after the formation<br />

of the customs union. Intra-bloc trade <strong>in</strong> manufactures is Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s major export. Its <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc<br />

exports value is more than 130 million US dollars after the transformation of the bloc <strong>in</strong>to a<br />

customs union. Agricultural raw material is Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s third major <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc export. However, it<br />

export value is less than 30 million US dollars after 2007. The export value of ores <strong>and</strong> metals,<br />

<strong>and</strong> fuels is less than 5 million dollars over the period.<br />

32


Figure 2.8 Show<strong>in</strong>g Stacked Graphs of Intra EAC Bloc Composition of Selected <strong>Products</strong> <strong>in</strong> Each Country<br />

Panel A: Figure 2.8.1 Burundi‟s Bloc Export Composition Panel B: Figure 2.8.2 Kenya‟s Bloc Export Composition<br />

Panel A: Figure 2.8.3 Rw<strong>and</strong>a‟s Bloc Export Composition Panel A: Figure 2.8.4 Tanzania‟s Bloc Export Composition<br />

Panel A: Figure 2.8.5 Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s Bloc Export Composition<br />

33


3.0 Literature Review<br />

3.1 Introduction<br />

Chapter Three<br />

In this section, the empirical, theoretical <strong>and</strong> methodological underp<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>gs are discussed. The<br />

first part of the section elucidates the def<strong>in</strong>itional <strong>and</strong> measurements concepts of the variables<br />

adopted <strong>in</strong> the study. And the section that follows reviews <strong>and</strong> profiles the theories that have<br />

been used to analyze trade between countries. In the third section, one of the theories is adopted<br />

<strong>and</strong> its theoretical <strong>and</strong> empirical underp<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>gs are discussed subsequently, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

attributes that made the study adopt it.<br />

3.2 Review of Def<strong>in</strong>itional Issues<br />

3.2.1 Def<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>and</strong> Measurement of the Effects of EI or RTAs<br />

Economic <strong>in</strong>tegration (sometimes known as <strong>Regional</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> Agreement – RTA or regional<br />

<strong>in</strong>tegration) <strong>in</strong>volves a collection of autarkical nations becom<strong>in</strong>g a fully <strong>in</strong>tegrated economic<br />

unit. In terms of a concrete def<strong>in</strong>ition, economic <strong>in</strong>tegration is the process by which a group of<br />

countries form closer economic l<strong>in</strong>ks with each other than with third countries or the rest of the<br />

world. Closer <strong>in</strong>tegration can, <strong>in</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciple, either be sectoral or general. Sectoral <strong>in</strong>tegration is<br />

where only specific sectors/<strong>in</strong>dustries with<strong>in</strong> an economy or bloc are <strong>in</strong>tegrated; general<br />

<strong>in</strong>tegration is where the entire economy or bloc is <strong>in</strong>tegrated (Vi-UNCTAD Teach<strong>in</strong>g Material<br />

on RTAs 2007). In either form, the <strong>in</strong>tegration does not only <strong>in</strong>volve the merg<strong>in</strong>g of economic<br />

attributes of the economy rang<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>in</strong>tegrat<strong>in</strong>g firms <strong>and</strong> sectors to converg<strong>in</strong>g bank<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

35


<strong>in</strong>vestment, education, tourism etc. sectors, but also <strong>in</strong>volve the converg<strong>in</strong>g of economic 9 <strong>and</strong><br />

political policies of the countries <strong>in</strong> the bloc at vary<strong>in</strong>g degrees.<br />

In captur<strong>in</strong>g the effect of RTAs <strong>in</strong> econometric models (especially gravity models),<br />

various authors (like Wanjiru 2006 , Jayas<strong>in</strong>ghe <strong>and</strong> Sarker, 2004, Cernat 2001 etc) have used an<br />

RTA dummy. Dummy variables serve several different uses <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g 10 ; the use or<br />

representation of several different categories or groups <strong>in</strong> a s<strong>in</strong>gle equation system, <strong>in</strong>stead of<br />

writ<strong>in</strong>g separate equations for each sub-category or group. More to this, much as a b<strong>in</strong>ary<br />

dummy 0,1is a nom<strong>in</strong>al level variable, it can be treated as an <strong>in</strong>terval-level variable statistically.<br />

A dummy variable (also called b<strong>in</strong>ary variable or a zero-one variable) is one that takes the values<br />

0 or 1 to <strong>in</strong>dicate the absence or presence of some categorical effect that may be expected to shift<br />

the outcome 11 . And the most important issue to measure a dummy variable is to assign a value<br />

one to one variable <strong>and</strong> zero to the other. And the name of the variable is the one that normally<br />

takes on the value one (Wooldridge, 2004). In essence, a value 0 is assigned if the variable or<br />

entity concerned is <strong>in</strong> the control group. A value 1 is prescribed to a variable or issue which falls<br />

<strong>in</strong> the group of <strong>in</strong>terest. For example, if one is study<strong>in</strong>g the EAC, all member states of the EAC<br />

would be ascribed a value 1 <strong>and</strong> member states of the ROW would be ascribed a value 0, to keep<br />

the dummy b<strong>in</strong>ary.<br />

In terms of measurements, the marg<strong>in</strong>al effect 12 of a dummy variable y is calculated as<br />

the discrete change <strong>in</strong> F(y) as the dummy variable y changes from 0 to 1. In terms of notation, it<br />

is signified <strong>in</strong> equation 1 below;<br />

Marg<strong>in</strong>al effect of y = F(y=1) - F(y=0) ………………..1<br />

9 Cited from www.dwaf.gov.za/Docs/Other/RISDP/Glossary.doc<br />

10 Cited from http://www.socialresearchmethods.net/kb/dummyvar.php<br />

11 Cited from wikipedia.org/wiki/Dummy variable_(statistics)<br />

12 Cited from http://www.stata.com/support/faqs/stat/mfx3.html - A detailed discussion of the dummies is <strong>in</strong> the<br />

methods section of this paper.<br />

36


3.2.2 Def<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>and</strong> Measurement of <strong>Agrifood</strong> or Food Items<br />

There are two major classifications of food items (also called agrifood products <strong>in</strong> this study).<br />

The two are by the International St<strong>and</strong>ards Industrial Classification (ISIC) <strong>and</strong> the other by UN‟<br />

SITC classification.<br />

The ISIC classification classifies food products as one of the compositions of aggregates<br />

of agriculture. ISIC makes classifications accord<strong>in</strong>g to economic activities.In this composition,<br />

the agriculture classification <strong>in</strong> this <strong>in</strong>cludes three products; Food <strong>Products</strong> (311), Beverages<br />

(313) <strong>and</strong> Tobacco (314).<br />

The other classification by the United Nations product classification for <strong>in</strong>ternational<br />

trade, def<strong>in</strong>es food item as the sum of SITC Codes (or CTCI codes) of 0, 1, 22 <strong>and</strong> 4. The<br />

statistics is detailed at the 3-digit level or by broad product group. 0 <strong>in</strong>cludes food <strong>and</strong> livestock,<br />

1 constitutes meat <strong>and</strong> meat preparations, while 22 is the composition of milk, cream <strong>and</strong> milk<br />

products (exclud<strong>in</strong>g butter <strong>and</strong> cheese); <strong>and</strong> 4 <strong>in</strong>corporates cereals <strong>and</strong> cereal preparations. This<br />

classification can be accessed from the H<strong>and</strong>book of Statistics referr<strong>in</strong>g to the St<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

International <strong>Trade</strong> Classification (SITC) Revision 3. See table 3.1 below for product details;<br />

Table 3.1: Composition of Food Item us<strong>in</strong>g the SITC Revision 3 (1 to 3 digits)<br />

Codes Food Item Product Group (0+1+22+4)<br />

0 Food & Live animals<br />

00 Live animals other than animals of division 03<br />

001 Live animals other than animals of division 03<br />

01 Meat <strong>and</strong> meat preparations<br />

011 Meat of bov<strong>in</strong>e animals, fresh, chilled or frozen<br />

012 Other meat <strong>and</strong> edible meat offal<br />

016 Meat, edible meat offal, salted, dried; flours, meals<br />

017 Meat, edible meat offal, prepared, preserved, n.e.s<br />

02 Dairy products <strong>and</strong> birds' egg<br />

022 Milk, cream <strong>and</strong> milk products (exclud<strong>in</strong>g butter, cheese)<br />

04 Cereals <strong>and</strong> cereal preparations<br />

041 Wheat (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g spelt) &mesl<strong>in</strong>, unmilled<br />

042 Rice<br />

043 Barley, unmilled<br />

044 Maize (not <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g sweet corn), unmilled<br />

045 Cereals, unmilled (exclud<strong>in</strong>g wheat, rice, barley, maize)<br />

046 Meal <strong>and</strong> flour of wheat <strong>and</strong> flour of mesl<strong>in</strong><br />

047 Other cereal meals <strong>and</strong> flour<br />

048 Cereal preparations, flour of fruits or vegetables<br />

Source: WITs <strong>and</strong> UNCTAD H<strong>and</strong>book of Statistics 2006 -2007<br />

37


The measurement of the values are <strong>in</strong> thous<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> gotten from World Integrated <strong>Trade</strong> System<br />

(WITS) under COMTRADE.<br />

The classification of food item between these two classifications has different<br />

compositions of the products <strong>in</strong> them. The study adopted the UN classification systems of SITC<br />

Revision.<br />

3.2.3 Def<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>and</strong> Specification Issues of Gravity<br />

The gravity model is a formulation that is used <strong>in</strong> calculat<strong>in</strong>g 13 the likely <strong>in</strong>teraction between two<br />

objects or groups of entities given the distance (or lack of connectivity) between them <strong>and</strong> their<br />

masses or sizes. The gravity model predicts flows between orig<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> dest<strong>in</strong>ation while tak<strong>in</strong>g<br />

cognizance of pair attributes <strong>in</strong> reference to the masses of the orig<strong>in</strong>-dest<strong>in</strong>ation attributes <strong>and</strong> the<br />

resistance for the pair to collate these attributes.<br />

It is named after its analogy with Newton‟s Universal Law of gravitation formulated<br />

as; where; F is gravitational force, M is mass <strong>and</strong> D is distance. That gravitational<br />

force between two objects depends on their masses <strong>and</strong> is <strong>in</strong>versely related to the square of the<br />

distance between them, all multiplied by a gravitation constant G (Keith 2003).<br />

3.3 Review of Theoretical Issues<br />

In the review of the literature, there seems to emanate three broad categories of theories to<br />

expla<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> measure trade between countries. However, these theories do not explicitly analyze<br />

trade <strong>in</strong> agrifood or food items. By design, they analyze trade <strong>in</strong> general merch<strong>and</strong>ise. However,<br />

they may be construed to study food item trade, especially the more recent ones that explicitly<br />

make the l<strong>in</strong>kages (through dummies or <strong>in</strong>corporat<strong>in</strong>g the agrifood products as endogenous<br />

flows) between RTAs <strong>and</strong> effects on agrifood trade.<br />

The three categories range from the formative trade theories named the classical or<br />

traditional trade theories. Classical trade theories assume that countries have comparative<br />

advantage (result<strong>in</strong>g from factor endowments) <strong>and</strong> as such, they specialize <strong>in</strong> the production of<br />

these products <strong>and</strong> trade them <strong>in</strong> exchange for the commodities they have comparative<br />

disadvantages. Their major weakness is to assume the labor theory of value (i.e. that labor is the<br />

only factor of production) <strong>and</strong> homogenous production <strong>in</strong> trade.<br />

However, relative factor abundance <strong>and</strong> technology <strong>in</strong>tensity could also <strong>in</strong>fluence<br />

productivity <strong>and</strong> even result <strong>in</strong> heterogeneous production. This realization bred <strong>in</strong>terest to modify<br />

13 Cited from www.tuition.com.hk/geography/g.htm<br />

38


the classical theories lead<strong>in</strong>g to a formation of a new range of theories called the Neo-classical<br />

trade theories. These theories assumed that <strong>in</strong>dustries are perfectively competitive <strong>and</strong> produced<br />

differentiated products (lead<strong>in</strong>g to Inter Industry <strong>Trade</strong> (IIT)). The major drawback of these<br />

theories is that they failed to expla<strong>in</strong> trade when <strong>in</strong>dustries are not perfectively competitive but<br />

monopolistically competitive. Due to this, a new broad categories of theories known as the New<br />

<strong>Trade</strong> Theories emerged. They assumed that trade was based on monopolistically competitive<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustries produc<strong>in</strong>g differentiated products (lead<strong>in</strong>g to Intra-Industry <strong>Trade</strong>). For a figurative<br />

view of the trade theories, see Table 3.2 below,<br />

Table 3.2 Evolution of trade theories<br />

Category of trade theory Presumptions<br />

Classical or Traditional trade theories<br />

1. Mercantilism (1500-1750) 1. Comparative Advantage<br />

2. Absolute advantage (by Adam Smith) 2. Labor theory of value<br />

3. Comparative advantage (by David Ricardo) 3. Specialization <strong>and</strong> factor endowments<br />

Neo -Classical trade theories<br />

1. Resource availability (Heckscher-Ohl<strong>in</strong>) 1. Perfectively competitive <strong>in</strong>dustries<br />

2. Richardo -V<strong>in</strong>er Models 2. Production of homogenous products<br />

3. Inter Industry <strong>Trade</strong><br />

'New trade theories' (1970s & 80s)<br />

i.e. new geography, external economies, gravity<br />

& econometric models etc.<br />

Sources: Developed for the study from literature<br />

3.3.1 Classical or Traditional Theories of International <strong>Trade</strong><br />

1. Monopolistically competitive<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustries<br />

2. Production of differentiated products<br />

3. Intra <strong>in</strong>dustry trade<br />

In table 3.2 above, the broad range of theories <strong>in</strong>itially developed <strong>in</strong> trade called the classical or<br />

traditional theories of trade. These theories assume that countries are different, <strong>and</strong> this<br />

difference expla<strong>in</strong>s why they would trade <strong>in</strong> different products 14 . That is, countries are endowed<br />

with a different set of resources (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g l<strong>and</strong>, capital, labor <strong>and</strong> entrepreneurship). And for the<br />

production of a particular product, that country will have a cost advantage. And as such, it will<br />

specialize <strong>in</strong> the production of that product, <strong>and</strong> this forms the basis of <strong>in</strong>ternational trade.<br />

14 Adopted from the follow<strong>in</strong>g cite http://benmuse.typepad.com/custom_house/trade_theory/<br />

39


These broad ranges of theories were developed start<strong>in</strong>g ma<strong>in</strong>ly with Adam Smith sem<strong>in</strong>al work<br />

on trade called the mercantile trade theory <strong>and</strong> later on the Absolute Advantage trade theory.<br />

Dur<strong>in</strong>g this, David Ricardo 15 also came up with a relatively superior trade theory called the<br />

comparative advantage theory with its modifications, which expla<strong>in</strong>ed trade when a country has<br />

not absolute advantage <strong>in</strong> any products relative to its partners. These three theories governed<br />

trade from the 16 th to the 18 th centuries.<br />

3.3.1.1 Mercantilist Theory of International <strong>Trade</strong><br />

The first known theory of trade was developed around 1500 – 1750, over three hundred years<br />

ago dur<strong>in</strong>g the „commercial revolution‟ that saw economies transform from; local to national,<br />

feudalism to capitalism <strong>and</strong> from rudimentary trade to projected <strong>in</strong>ternational trade. Mercantilism<br />

emphasized that a country keeps a positive trade balance that would secure or safeguard the<br />

country dur<strong>in</strong>g war or guarantee prosperity. And to keep a positive or even maximize a positive<br />

trade balance, it promoted exports <strong>and</strong> discouraged imports 16 . Dur<strong>in</strong>g this period, there was no<br />

mutually beneficial trade, as one country ga<strong>in</strong>ed at the expense of another (the surplus was<br />

accumulated at the expense of the partner), e.g. dur<strong>in</strong>g the colonial expansion by European<br />

countries. As such, mercantilist trade policy was viewed as „zero-sum‟ game. It led to<br />

resentments, revolts <strong>and</strong> progressive wars that made such a practice or idea untenable. Over time,<br />

mercantilism trade theory lost its appeal, <strong>and</strong> was readily replaced by yet another theory - the<br />

theory of comparative advantage. It should be noted that mercantile policies are practiced at least<br />

by some firms do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>and</strong> it new supporters are known as „neo-mercantilists‟ or<br />

„protectionists‟ (Mahoney, et al, 1998).<br />

3.3.1.2 Absolute Advantage <strong>and</strong> Comparative Advantage Theory of International <strong>Trade</strong><br />

The collapse of the mercantilist ideas ga<strong>in</strong>ed root with the evolution of the <strong>in</strong>dustrial age <strong>and</strong><br />

capitalism <strong>in</strong> Europe that saw it as a h<strong>in</strong>drance to advancement. The trade theories that arose at<br />

the twilight of the mercantilist theory emphasized „w<strong>in</strong>-w<strong>in</strong>‟ outcomes <strong>in</strong>stead of „zero-sum‟<br />

outcomes <strong>in</strong> trade. Adam Smith was aga<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>strumental at the dawn of these trade theories that<br />

emphasized „w<strong>in</strong>-w<strong>in</strong>‟ trade outcomes when he propounded the absolute advantage theory. The<br />

idea beh<strong>in</strong>d this theory was that a trade regime could be changed by produc<strong>in</strong>g only commodities<br />

of absolute advantage <strong>and</strong> exchange (trade) the surplus of this process with a trad<strong>in</strong>g partner who<br />

specializes <strong>in</strong> produc<strong>in</strong>g commodities that are domestically expensive to produce, hence<br />

benefit<strong>in</strong>g also consumers. Intuitive as it was, the theory failed to expla<strong>in</strong> the pattern <strong>and</strong> ga<strong>in</strong>s<br />

15 Cited from http://www.vazecollege.net/tyeco.html<br />

16 Cited from http://www.oppapers.com/essays/International-<strong>Trade</strong>-Theories/179424<br />

40


from trade when a country is disadvantage <strong>in</strong> all ranges of products. More to this, it only<br />

expla<strong>in</strong>ed a small part of world trade <strong>and</strong> it is seen as a special case of the more general theory of<br />

trade based on comparative advantage.<br />

David Richardo <strong>in</strong>troduced the comparative advantage theory, a ref<strong>in</strong>ement of the<br />

absolute advantage theory. Comparative advantage models differ <strong>in</strong> structure but all aim at<br />

expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the pattern of <strong>and</strong> ga<strong>in</strong>s from trade (<strong>in</strong>ter <strong>in</strong>dustry). Customary, they were based on<br />

the law of comparative advantage (Either 1983 <strong>and</strong> Salvatore 2004) which provideda solution to<br />

the impasse created by the absolute advantage theory. And it specifies that mutually beneficial<br />

trade can still occur between two nations even if a country is less efficient <strong>in</strong> the production of<br />

two commodities. This is enabled when each nation specializes <strong>and</strong> trades (or exports) the<br />

commodity <strong>in</strong> which it has less comparative disadvantage <strong>and</strong> import the commodity of more<br />

comparative disadvantage. The exception to this (which is very rare), is when both nations have<br />

the same level of absolute disadvantage. In such a case, trade will not occur s<strong>in</strong>ce there is no<br />

comparative advantage or disadvantage <strong>in</strong> the production of both commodities <strong>in</strong> both nations. In<br />

light of such <strong>in</strong>tricacies, there was a need to reestablish the theory. That is, <strong>in</strong> the absence of<br />

equivalent levels of comparative advantage between trad<strong>in</strong>g partners for the products they trade,<br />

mutual <strong>and</strong> beneficial trade <strong>and</strong> exchange of trade <strong>in</strong> those commodities could take place when<br />

each of the said countries specialize <strong>in</strong> the production <strong>and</strong> exchange the products it has less<br />

absolute advantage.<br />

Later on, there was recognition of the short com<strong>in</strong>gs of the theory of comparative<br />

advantage <strong>and</strong> it was modified by <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g opportunity costs. In modify<strong>in</strong>g this, there was an<br />

assumption of the labor theory of value – which assumes that labor is the only factor of<br />

production. It presumed that labor was used <strong>in</strong> the same fixed proportion for produc<strong>in</strong>g all<br />

commodities, s<strong>in</strong>ce it was homogeneous. As such, the commodity prices depended exclusively<br />

on the quantity of labor utilized <strong>in</strong> production. The new modification stated that, a country<br />

should specialize <strong>and</strong> export the commodity it has a lower opportunity cost than another <strong>and</strong><br />

import the commodity with a higher opportunity cost. The notion beh<strong>in</strong>d this is simple, because,<br />

when opportunity costs that differ between the countries but are constant with<strong>in</strong> each country are<br />

considered for a factor, then the country with a lower sacrifice (opportunity cost) <strong>in</strong> that<br />

factorspecializes <strong>in</strong> produc<strong>in</strong>g a certa<strong>in</strong> commodity <strong>and</strong> exchanges it with the other country‟s<br />

commodity, s<strong>in</strong>ce the lower sacrifice enables it to have a comparative advantage <strong>in</strong> produc<strong>in</strong>gthat<br />

commodity. Therefore, the difference <strong>in</strong> opportunity costs forms the basis for trade. However, <strong>in</strong><br />

time, major flaws were also cited <strong>in</strong> these models: First, the models imply complete<br />

specialization <strong>in</strong> production, which is not tenable; secondly, there is an assumption of a s<strong>in</strong>gle<br />

factor of production. Countries produce major production simultaneously, <strong>and</strong> further, the<br />

models fail to <strong>in</strong>corporate <strong>in</strong>come distributions issues <strong>and</strong> there is doubt that assumption of<br />

technological differences are posit <strong>in</strong> the long run across countries.<br />

41


3.3.2 Neo-Classical or St<strong>and</strong>ard <strong>Trade</strong> Theories<br />

The fail<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> the classical trade theories gave rise to a new group of theories known as the neoclassical<br />

or st<strong>and</strong>ard trade theories. The st<strong>and</strong>ard trade models assume that there is a variant of<br />

factors of production, an issue not considered <strong>in</strong> the classical trade theories. And that the<br />

difference <strong>in</strong> resources can drive the trade patterns <strong>and</strong> this affects the distribution of resources<br />

(Krugman <strong>and</strong> Obstfeld, 2009). The two major models that fall <strong>in</strong> this category are the<br />

Heckscher - Ohl<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> Ricardo-V<strong>in</strong>er models. The Heckscher - Ohl<strong>in</strong> model assumes that factor<br />

abundance will determ<strong>in</strong>e the pattern of <strong>and</strong> ga<strong>in</strong>s from trade <strong>in</strong> those products it is endowed<br />

with. This is because they will have a comparative advantage <strong>in</strong> produc<strong>in</strong>g those products.<br />

However, this could only hold if the economy‟s major sectors have wages above the subsistence<br />

level (Vylder 2007). While the Ricardo-V<strong>in</strong>er model emphasizes the fact that trade patterns will<br />

be reflected by factor abundance across countries when production technologies are identical<br />

across countries.<br />

Intuitive as these models are, they still failed to estimate trade fully s<strong>in</strong>ce issues that<br />

affect political debated (like migration, growth, transit costs, <strong>and</strong> network effects) today were<br />

still exogenous to these models 17 , hence a rise of a totally new group of theories after the Second<br />

World War.<br />

3.3.3 New <strong>Trade</strong> Theories <strong>and</strong> new development <strong>in</strong> Analyz<strong>in</strong>g International <strong>Trade</strong><br />

The end of the Second War led to massive changes <strong>in</strong> the structure of the world. For example,<br />

most countries synergized their <strong>in</strong>dustrials, sectors <strong>and</strong> policies by <strong>in</strong>tegrat<strong>in</strong>g. This new<br />

paradigm necessitated a formulation of new theories that endogenised pert<strong>in</strong>ent issues of this<br />

new era like migration, transport costs, networks etc. In the 1970s <strong>and</strong> 1980s, new trade theories<br />

were formulated, <strong>and</strong> they were broadly labeled the New <strong>Trade</strong> Theories (NTT) 18 .<br />

It has been argued that the only unique or new th<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the NTT was their mathematical<br />

rigor that <strong>in</strong>cluded tacit use of protectionism. They too considered <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g returns to scale that<br />

enable firms, <strong>in</strong>dustries or sectors to build a huge competitive world market base. The other<br />

presumptions relate to the emphasis of NTT on networks (ma<strong>in</strong>ly their effect), <strong>and</strong><br />

monopolistically competitive <strong>in</strong>dustries produc<strong>in</strong>g differentiated products. These<br />

monopolistically competitive <strong>in</strong>dustries engaged <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>tra-<strong>in</strong>dustry-trade 19 (exchange of same<br />

product but of different variety) (Krugman <strong>and</strong> Obstfeld, 2009).<br />

17 Cited from http://www.marg<strong>in</strong>alrevolution.com/marg<strong>in</strong>alrevolution/2008/10/what-is-new-tra.html<br />

18 Cited from http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/New_<strong>Trade</strong>_Theory<br />

19 Previous theories presumed perfectly competitive <strong>in</strong>dustries engag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ter-<strong>in</strong>dustry trade (i.e. trad<strong>in</strong>g one<br />

product for another).<br />

42


At their evolution, the models of the NTT lacked sufficient dataset to test them<br />

empirically. Further, besides be<strong>in</strong>g too technical, empirically produced mixed results <strong>and</strong> the<br />

reliability produc<strong>in</strong>g mix results, the statistical judgments from them were hard to fathom. More<br />

to this, the time-scales required <strong>and</strong> the particular nature of production <strong>in</strong> each 'monopolizable'<br />

sector was subjective to the researchers 20 .<br />

Prior to the evolution of the NTT, there was <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong>terest that stemmed to analyze<br />

the outcome of RTAs or EIs specifically. And traditionally, this economic analysis evaluated the<br />

desirability of regional <strong>in</strong>tegration arrangements accord<strong>in</strong>g to their trade diversion <strong>and</strong> trade<br />

creation effects (Shams 2003). V<strong>in</strong>er‟s sem<strong>in</strong>al work on trade creation <strong>and</strong> diversion effects <strong>in</strong><br />

1950, noted that trade creation occurs when imports are substituted for domestic products as a<br />

result of tariff reductions that reduce the price of member imports below that of home-produced<br />

goods. While trade diversion transpires with a shift <strong>in</strong> imports from an efficient non-member<br />

exporter to a more expensive producer from the country‟s RTAs partners due to preferential<br />

tariff treatment. <strong>Trade</strong> diversion, <strong>in</strong> V<strong>in</strong>er‟s view, did not necessarily mean a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> trade, but<br />

rather a shift <strong>in</strong> trade away from the least cost suppliers. Contemporary writers simply state that,<br />

trade creation occurs if partner country production displaces higher cost domestic production.<br />

And trade diversion implies that partner country production displaces lower cost imports from<br />

third countries. <strong>Trade</strong> diversion is said to <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc trade at the expense of trade with<br />

third countries, while trade creation does not have this negative effect. Therefore a regional trade<br />

arrangement is only desirable if trade creation outweighs trade diversion (Shams 2002).<br />

Furthermore, the economic effect of form<strong>in</strong>g RTAs (accord<strong>in</strong>g to the Neo-classical<br />

theory) depended on whether it was „shallow or deep <strong>in</strong>tegration‟ too (UNCTAD Teach<strong>in</strong>g<br />

material on RTA, 2007). A shallow or negative <strong>in</strong>tegration, <strong>in</strong>volves the removal of border<br />

barriers to trade, typically tariffs <strong>and</strong> quotas. While deep or positive <strong>in</strong>tegration, <strong>in</strong>volves policies<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutions that facilitate trade by reduc<strong>in</strong>g or elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g of regulatory <strong>and</strong> beh<strong>in</strong>d-theborder<br />

impediments to trade, where those impediments may or may not be <strong>in</strong>tentional. The<br />

cont<strong>in</strong>uum of policies could <strong>in</strong>clude, customs procedures, regulation or domestic services<br />

production that discrim<strong>in</strong>ate aga<strong>in</strong>st foreigners, product st<strong>and</strong>ards that differ from <strong>in</strong>ternational<br />

norms or where test<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> certification of foreign goods is complex <strong>and</strong> perhaps exclusionary,<br />

regulation of <strong>in</strong>ward <strong>in</strong>vestments, competition policy, <strong>in</strong>tellectual policy protection <strong>and</strong> the rules<br />

surround<strong>in</strong>g access to government procurement.<br />

Another model that developed dur<strong>in</strong>g this same period is the Gravity model 21 . And it has<br />

been widely used <strong>in</strong> analyz<strong>in</strong>g trad<strong>in</strong>g patterns better than many of the theoretical models on<br />

trade. The gravity model, tries to <strong>in</strong>corporate a broad range of covariates lack<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> theoretical<br />

models discussed above. Furthermore, the gravity analysis <strong>and</strong> model has ga<strong>in</strong>ed supremacy due<br />

20 Ibid<br />

21 Cited from http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/International_trade<br />

43


to the fact that it has a predictable role as a tool used <strong>in</strong> estimat<strong>in</strong>g effects of a variety of<br />

phenomena <strong>in</strong> social sciences. In economics <strong>and</strong> especially <strong>in</strong>ternational trade, it is a successful<br />

model<strong>in</strong>g approach for various reasons; the results from it have high explanatory power of<br />

between 0.65 <strong>and</strong> 0.95 <strong>and</strong> are sensible (especially on distance <strong>and</strong> output), economically <strong>and</strong><br />

statistically significant. Also, there is easy access to bilateral trade data, <strong>and</strong> the model expla<strong>in</strong>s<br />

most of the variations <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational trade. Estimation st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>and</strong> benchmarks of the gravity<br />

model have been clearly established. The next section reviews the build - up of the theoretical<br />

construction of the model <strong>in</strong> detail.<br />

3.4 Review of Theoretical Foundation of Gravity Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>Trade</strong>.<br />

The gravity model has been used to model many social <strong>in</strong>teractions like tourism, migration, trade<br />

<strong>and</strong> foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestment (FDI). They are econometric models which use ex-post analysis.<br />

And <strong>in</strong> trade, by design they are macro models s<strong>in</strong>ce they are used to capture volume rather than<br />

composition of bilateral trade (Appleyard <strong>and</strong> Field 2001).<br />

When it was <strong>in</strong>troduced to trade by T<strong>in</strong>bergen 1962, it had no theoretical foundation. He<br />

proposed that the same functional form (as seen above) that could be applied to <strong>in</strong>ternational<br />

trade flows specified as;<br />

1<br />

Where; X are exports from I to j or total trade (it could either represent a flow from orig<strong>in</strong> (i) to<br />

dest<strong>in</strong>ation (j), or total volume of <strong>in</strong>terruptions between I <strong>and</strong> j. Some authors like Rose, 2004<br />

use average trade volume), Y economic size (proxies are gross domestic product or gross<br />

national <strong>in</strong>come, Population); T is trade cost (proxies are distance, common language, colonial<br />

l<strong>in</strong>k, common currency, isl<strong>and</strong> or l<strong>and</strong> locked). In the orig<strong>in</strong> Newton model it is called distance.<br />

However <strong>in</strong> trade, we look at economic distance i.e. a sort of tax „wedge‟ impos<strong>in</strong>g trade costs,<br />

<strong>and</strong> result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> lower equilibrium trade flows.<br />

Model one above states that, bilateral trade between country i <strong>and</strong>j is <strong>in</strong>versely related to<br />

distance <strong>and</strong> positively enhanced by their sizes. The multiplicative nature of the gravity equation<br />

means that we can take natural logs <strong>and</strong> obta<strong>in</strong> a l<strong>in</strong>ear relationship between trade flows <strong>and</strong> the<br />

logged economy sizes <strong>and</strong> distances 22 i.e.<br />

22 Head, Keith (2003). Gravity for Beg<strong>in</strong>ners. Cited from


The <strong>in</strong>clusion of the error term <strong>in</strong> equation 2 above delivers an equation that can be estimated<br />

by ord<strong>in</strong>ary least squares regression (OLS).<br />

Deardorff (1998) was among the first persons to develop its theoretical foundation <strong>and</strong> he<br />

suspects ‘justabout any plausible model of trade would yield someth<strong>in</strong>g very much like the<br />

gravity model.’ Anderson <strong>and</strong> Van W<strong>in</strong>coop (2003) too re<strong>in</strong>-enforced theoretical foundations <strong>and</strong><br />

concluded <strong>in</strong> their proof that,„bilateral trade is determ<strong>in</strong>ed by relative trade costs’. Other major<br />

contributions were by; Anderson 1979 when he emphasized the Arm<strong>in</strong>gton hypothesis (i.e.<br />

goods differentiated by country of orig<strong>in</strong>), Bergstr<strong>and</strong> 1990 when he considered monopolistic<br />

competition <strong>and</strong> price <strong>in</strong>dices be<strong>in</strong>g those used <strong>in</strong> practice <strong>and</strong> not the ones suggested by theory.<br />

3.5 Review of Methodological <strong>and</strong> Empirical Issues<br />

The grow<strong>in</strong>g myriad of RTAs negotiations have yet to address the issue of drastically decreas<strong>in</strong>g<br />

tariffs on food products, as they have done for merch<strong>and</strong>ise trade. Recent negotiations, have even<br />

led to reductions <strong>in</strong> agricultural raw materials but not food item trade. Further, exist<strong>in</strong>g literature<br />

does not adequately provide evidence of trade <strong>in</strong> agrifood products or food item trade<br />

(Jayas<strong>in</strong>ghe <strong>and</strong> Sarker 2004). The few empirical studies enlisted below, have ma<strong>in</strong>ly used three<br />

approaches to estimate the impact of RTAs on food item trade. These three are approaches are,<br />

the econometrics approaches, computable general equilibrium (CGE) <strong>and</strong> descriptive<br />

approaches. Of these approaches, the econometric approaches employ<strong>in</strong>g the gravity model<strong>in</strong>g<br />

are the most frequent, as enlisted below. Studies employ<strong>in</strong>g the CGE models have hardly been<br />

found. And those that use descriptive are <strong>in</strong>adequate to capture trade effects, s<strong>in</strong>ce they are not<br />

robust.<br />

The consensus from these studies is that regional <strong>in</strong>tegration has a positive effect on trade<br />

<strong>in</strong> agrifood trade. That they <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc trade tends to <strong>in</strong>crease, however, at the expense of trade<br />

with the ROW. Nonetheless, there are mixed f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs on the whether the RTAs promote bloc<br />

export or imports. For example, Jayas<strong>in</strong>ghe <strong>and</strong> Sarker, 2004, <strong>in</strong> study<strong>in</strong>g the effects of RTAs on<br />

trade on agrifood products, concluded that, NAFTA boosted <strong>in</strong>tra-regional trade <strong>in</strong> agrifood<br />

products. However, this was achieved at the expense of trade <strong>in</strong> the same products with the rest<br />

of the world. That is, those NAFTA member countries have moved towards a lower degree of<br />

openness with the world. The results that led to this conclusion were produced us<strong>in</strong>g gravity<br />

model<strong>in</strong>g. The dataset used was disaggregated <strong>and</strong> they focused on the pooled cross-section time<br />

series regressions <strong>and</strong> generalized least squares methods. They choose six products <strong>and</strong> run the<br />

different regressions with the product volumes as dependent variables.<br />

The study by Sarker <strong>and</strong> Jayas<strong>in</strong>ghe, 2007, also uses the gravity models to estimate<br />

European Union RTA <strong>and</strong> impact of trade <strong>in</strong> agrifood products. They also <strong>in</strong>clude six products as<br />

<strong>in</strong> their earlier study <strong>and</strong> proceed <strong>in</strong> their estimations as described above. They estimate the<br />

45


esults us<strong>in</strong>g an extended gravity model with pooled data. The data run from 1985 to 2000 <strong>and</strong><br />

they used the GLS method. They conclude that, EU‟s trade <strong>in</strong> agrifood products <strong>in</strong> the mid1980s<br />

was also boosted significantly among its members. Nevertheless, this is be<strong>in</strong>g boosted at the<br />

expense of the rest of the world.<br />

Another study analyz<strong>in</strong>g EU agrifood trade was done by Serrano <strong>and</strong> P<strong>in</strong>illa (2010). They<br />

estimated EU agrifood trade from 1963 to 2000 us<strong>in</strong>g disaggregated data for products<br />

decomposed as trade. They also concluded that <strong>in</strong>tra-EU growth significantly boosted trade <strong>in</strong><br />

agrifood products. They further concluded that the trade was also export <strong>and</strong> import food trade<br />

was significantly boosted. To estimate the results that led to such a conclusion, they too<br />

employed an extended gravity model. They run it with fixed effects <strong>and</strong> employed the Prais-<br />

Weste<strong>in</strong> estimation technique.<br />

In another study by Dissanayake <strong>and</strong> Weerahawa, (2009), on the trade creation <strong>and</strong> trade<br />

diversion effects of agricultural trade, conclude that the SAPTA led to more trade <strong>in</strong> food exports<br />

<strong>and</strong> that this trade was beneficial to SAPTA member states. However, <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc food<br />

trade led to export diversion. They too, used an extended gravity model to quantify the effects of<br />

trade creation <strong>and</strong> diversion agricultural trade. In the gravity model they specified, they run it<br />

with cross-sectional data <strong>and</strong> run it with fixed effects.<br />

However, Grant <strong>and</strong> Lamber (2005), make an <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g that NAFTA led to trade<br />

creation of over 75 percent of 8 out of the 9 products <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> their study. And this was<br />

created with little or no trade diversion with the rest of the world. They recommend that RTAs<br />

are an attractive alternative for countries to „multilateralism‟ their agriculture. They were<br />

study<strong>in</strong>g regionalism <strong>in</strong> world agriculture. They used the gravity model to estimate the<br />

magnitude of this trade creation <strong>and</strong> trade diversion.<br />

Another set of studies is that by Dell‟Aquila, ettal (1999) <strong>and</strong> Diao, et al (1999), who use<br />

descriptive studies to study the effect of RTAs on agrifood trade. They also concluded that <strong>in</strong>traregional<br />

trade <strong>in</strong> agrifood products was boosted because of RTAs <strong>in</strong> time. The latter study‟s<br />

conclusion of <strong>in</strong>tra-regional trade be<strong>in</strong>g boosted was with reference to the rest of the world. It<br />

also studied the NAFTA, EU-15, Mercusor <strong>and</strong> APEE. However, the major drawback of the<br />

descriptive studies is that they are not robust <strong>and</strong> cannot capture trade effects.<br />

3.6 Conclusion <strong>and</strong> Relevance of the Literature Review<br />

In this section, the study reviewed the evolution of the trade models <strong>and</strong> zeroed on to the gravity<br />

model. The review h<strong>in</strong>ged on the theoretical underp<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> also the empirical evolution. The<br />

gravity model was found to have strong theoretical foundations <strong>and</strong> its empirical use was quite<br />

vast, <strong>and</strong> it was the major model used to analyze specifically food item trade <strong>in</strong> RTAs. The<br />

model had a strong explanatory power for trade, was economically <strong>and</strong> statistically significant.<br />

46


This provides me the impetus to adopt it to study the case for EAC <strong>in</strong> sectoral <strong>and</strong> specifically<br />

food item trade.<br />

From the theoretical <strong>and</strong> empirical developments of the gravity model <strong>in</strong> previous<br />

sections, it has ga<strong>in</strong>ed supremacy due to the fact that it has a predictable role as a tool used <strong>in</strong><br />

estimat<strong>in</strong>g effects of a variety of phenomena <strong>in</strong> social sciences. In economics <strong>and</strong> especially<br />

<strong>in</strong>ternational trade, it is a successful model<strong>in</strong>g approach for various reasons; the results from it<br />

have high explanatory power of between 0.65 <strong>and</strong> 0.95 <strong>and</strong> are sensible (especially on distance<br />

<strong>and</strong> output), economically <strong>and</strong> statistically significant. Also, there is easy access to bilateral trade<br />

data, <strong>and</strong> the model expla<strong>in</strong>s most of the variations <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational trade. Estimation st<strong>and</strong>ards<br />

<strong>and</strong> benchmarks of the gravity model have been clearly established.<br />

47


Chapter Four<br />

4.0 Analytical Framework <strong>and</strong> Methodology<br />

4.1 Introduction<br />

In this chapter, the analytical framework of the study is described <strong>in</strong> section 4.1. The specified<br />

empirical equations <strong>and</strong> the variables <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the models are expounded on <strong>in</strong> section 4.2. In<br />

section 4.3 the types <strong>and</strong> sources of data are expla<strong>in</strong>ed too.<br />

4.2 Analytical Framework: Gravity Model<br />

This study adopted with modifications, Subramanian <strong>and</strong> Wei, 2003 extended gravity model<br />

specification. The modifications relate to dropp<strong>in</strong>g some covariates <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g new ones not<br />

used <strong>in</strong> their study. Further, it replicates this approach for EAC us<strong>in</strong>g different products of EAC<br />

<strong>in</strong>terest <strong>and</strong> different time periods of its formation. The general specification is of the follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

form;<br />

The model has seven components namely:<br />

Component one, which <strong>in</strong>cludes all the covariates used <strong>in</strong><br />

Subramanian <strong>and</strong> Wei, 2003, <strong>and</strong> captures trade between EAC member states <strong>and</strong> the rest of<br />

the world that depends on policy <strong>and</strong> physical barriers. These are the normal covariates <strong>in</strong> a<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard gravity model <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g; log of GDP, log of GDP per capita, log l<strong>and</strong> area of<br />

48


exporters <strong>and</strong> importers, greater circle distance between i <strong>and</strong> j, dummies for common<br />

language, <strong>and</strong> colonial l<strong>in</strong>ks, shared borders, currency, <strong>and</strong> a dummy for l<strong>and</strong>locked.<br />

The other two components termed multilateral resistances are<br />

used to capture or proxy trade between the export<strong>in</strong>g EAC countries <strong>and</strong> the import<strong>in</strong>g world;<br />

a. Where is a list of importer dummies tak<strong>in</strong>g the value of one if i = j, <strong>and</strong> zero<br />

otherwise.<br />

b. While is a list of exporter dummies tak<strong>in</strong>g the value of one if h = i, <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise.<br />

The third component is a set of dummy variables takes<br />

on a value of 1 if i is equal to j. It also specified <strong>in</strong> a way that it captures counterfactual trade<br />

or change <strong>in</strong> the composition of the trad<strong>in</strong>g bloc.<br />

The fifth segment of the model is, , the key focus<br />

of the study, that would capture the sectoral composition of the chosen sectors of EAC trade<br />

<strong>in</strong>terest. The food item or agrifood trade is taken as the base sector.<br />

Related to this, is the component, , that<br />

captures exporter effects or the component the EAC trade liberalization that is absorbed by<br />

each country.<br />

And the, which is a normally distributed r<strong>and</strong>om term that<br />

has a zero mean <strong>and</strong> a constant variance.<br />

4.3 Specification of Empirical Equations<br />

Follow<strong>in</strong>g Carrere (2006) <strong>and</strong> Subramanian <strong>and</strong> Wei (2003), the above analytical framework is<br />

decomposed to the follow<strong>in</strong>g specification:<br />

Where expected signs: , , , , 0, , , , 0<br />

The above equation was run to answer four research questions. The first question relates<br />

to estimat<strong>in</strong>g the effect of the adopted trade liberalization policy <strong>and</strong> determ<strong>in</strong>es which<br />

covariates expla<strong>in</strong> bloc trade, especially the EAC dummy covariate, at the region <strong>and</strong> country<br />

49


levels? Apriori, the signs on the dummies may not be determ<strong>in</strong>ed. The expected signs of the<br />

other covariates are determ<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> other sections of the paper. The second question is to what<br />

extent the EAC trade liberalization efforts affects its <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc trad<strong>in</strong>g patterns of the selected<br />

sectors? A priori, the expected change is positive because it is widely believed that the formation<br />

of EAC <strong>and</strong> its membership marked a watershed <strong>in</strong> the status of EAC trad<strong>in</strong>g. This question is<br />

modified when counterfactual trade is <strong>in</strong>cluded, i.e., <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g other members who normally<br />

trade as EAC though they are not formally members. And the key proposition the study<br />

addresses under this was whether EAC membership has a differential impact for the sectors<br />

chosen. And the food sub sector was used as a base dummy. The third issue is estimate the<br />

impact of EAC trade liberalization on <strong>in</strong>tra-regional, export <strong>and</strong> imports of trade <strong>and</strong> hence<br />

implication on trade creation <strong>and</strong> trade liberalization? And fourthly, how is the trade<br />

liberalization effect distributed across each country?<br />

However, to estimate or analyze the distribution on the five EAC member states, equation<br />

5 is modified <strong>and</strong> equation 6 below is run for all the five countries.<br />

4.3.1 Coefficients <strong>and</strong> Variable Def<strong>in</strong>ition<br />

4.3.1.1 Coefficients Def<strong>in</strong>ition<br />

The variables embedded <strong>in</strong> these models <strong>in</strong>clude the β, δ, ϑ <strong>and</strong> ϕ coefficients estimates from the<br />

normal gravity model covariates, EAC dummies, sectoral dummies <strong>and</strong> exporter country<br />

dummies respectively. They show the major effects of each covariate on the exports.<br />

The EAC dummy is specified <strong>in</strong> three forms, follow<strong>in</strong>g Egger, 2002 <strong>and</strong> Soloaga <strong>and</strong><br />

W<strong>in</strong>ters, 2001 to formulate a correct ex-post assessment of the effect of the volume of trade,<br />

namely;<br />

a. To capture <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc trade, a dummy of both-<strong>in</strong> , where δ is equal to one if both<br />

partners belong to the same RTA <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise, is <strong>in</strong>troduced.<br />

50


. To capture bloc imports from the rest of the world, a dummy equal one if import<strong>in</strong>g<br />

country j belongs to the RTA <strong>and</strong> export<strong>in</strong>g country i belong to the rest of the world, <strong>and</strong> zero<br />

otherwise, is also <strong>in</strong>troduced.<br />

c. And another dummy captur<strong>in</strong>g bloc exports to the rest of the world equal to one if<br />

export<strong>in</strong>g country i belong to the RTA <strong>and</strong> import<strong>in</strong>g country j belongs to the rest of the world,<br />

<strong>and</strong> zero otherwise is also <strong>in</strong>troduced.<br />

If the <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc trade > 0, it means that <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc trade has <strong>in</strong>creased more than predicted<br />

by the reference which can be <strong>in</strong> substitution to domestic production or to exports from the rest<br />

of the world. As to whether this corresponds to trade creation (TC) or trade diversion (TD), one<br />

needs to exam<strong>in</strong>e the sign of the coefficients <strong>and</strong> . <strong>Trade</strong> is diverted when > 0 <strong>and</strong><br />

< 0 (<strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g a low propensity to import from the rest of the world), <strong>and</strong> when this negative<br />

propensity to import from the rest of the world entirely offsets the <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc trade enhancement,<br />

this is pure trade diversion. However, when <strong>in</strong>tra-regional trade <strong>in</strong>creases more than imports<br />

from the rest of the world decreases, there is both trade creation <strong>and</strong> trade diversion. In this case,<br />

if > 0 <strong>and</strong> ≥ 0, this is a case of pure trade creation. Accord<strong>in</strong>g Carrere, 2004, <strong>in</strong>ference<br />

on welfare to non-members could be deduced on compar<strong>in</strong>g the coefficients <strong>and</strong> . That is,<br />

welfare is decreased for non members when > 0 <strong>and</strong> < 0, which <strong>in</strong>dicates a dom<strong>in</strong>ant<br />

export diversion. So then, trade is purely created when > 0 <strong>and</strong> ≥ 0 when also ≥ 0.<br />

And trade is purely diverted when > 0 <strong>and</strong>


4.3.1.2 Variables Def<strong>in</strong>itions<br />

In this section, <strong>in</strong>formation is provided on the label of the variables <strong>and</strong> their measurements. The range of variables used is;<br />

Table 4.1 Show<strong>in</strong>g the Description of the Variables <strong>and</strong> Their Measurement<br />

Variable<br />

Name Units or Variable Label Description <strong>and</strong> Variable Label<br />

Source of<br />

Data<br />

iso code<br />

Country Codes PWT 7.0<br />

Year Year Years rang<strong>in</strong>g from 1988 to 2009 PWT 7.0<br />

pop Thous<strong>and</strong>s Population (<strong>in</strong> thous<strong>and</strong>s) of the countries under study PWT 7.0<br />

The value of Imports (reported as exports from EAC members states) UN<br />

that EAC trad<strong>in</strong>g partners (ROW) report as emanat<strong>in</strong>g from EAC COMTRADE<br />

Exports Thous<strong>and</strong>s of USD<br />

members states<br />

- WITS<br />

XRAT national currency units per US dollar Exchange Rate to US$ PWT 7.0<br />

million International dollar (million Total PPP Converted GDP, G-K method, at current prices (<strong>in</strong> millions<br />

tcgdp I$)<br />

I$) PWT 7.0<br />

cgdp International dollar (I$) PPP Converted GDP Per Capita, G-K method, at current prices (<strong>in</strong> I$)<br />

Common Language Dummies<br />

PWT 7.0<br />

comlang_off Common official Language<br />

Dummy variable equal to one if two countries share a common official<br />

language or share languages spoken by at least 20% of the population<br />

of the country CEPII<br />

comlang_entho Common language ethnographic<br />

Dummy variable equal to oneif a language is spoken by at least 9% of<br />

the population <strong>in</strong> both countries<br />

Simple Distance Measures<br />

CEPII<br />

dist distance<br />

CEPII<br />

distcap distance between capitals Distance between capitals follow<strong>in</strong>g the great circle formula<br />

Country Pair Similarity Dummies<br />

CEPII<br />

contig Two countries be<strong>in</strong>g contiguous Dummy variables <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g whether the two countries are contiguous CEPII<br />

l<strong>and</strong>locked L<strong>and</strong>locked Dummy variable set equal to 1 for l<strong>and</strong>locked countries CEPII<br />

52


colony Colonial l<strong>in</strong>k<br />

comcol Common Colonizer<br />

curcol<br />

smctry Same country<br />

Dummy variable <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g whether the country pair have ever had a<br />

colonial l<strong>in</strong>k CEPII<br />

Dummy variable <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that the country pair have had a common<br />

colonizer after 1945 CEPII<br />

Dummy variable <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g whether the country pair are currently <strong>in</strong> a<br />

colonial relationship CEPII<br />

Dummy variable equal to 1 if countries were or are the same state or<br />

the same adm<strong>in</strong>istrative entity for a long period (25-50 years <strong>in</strong> the<br />

twentieth century, 75 year <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>etieth <strong>and</strong> 100 years before). CEPII<br />

Notes: In the study, exporter or importer is pegged on the variable name or I & j , rep (reporter) & Partner is used for this dist<strong>in</strong>ction<br />

53


4.4 Method of Analysis<br />

For this empirical economic research, the focus was to estimate the bilateral trade<br />

relations of EAC <strong>in</strong>tra – regional trade. S<strong>in</strong>ce the study did not <strong>in</strong>clude tariff data, it does not<br />

estimate <strong>in</strong>ter – regional trade impact. In the estimation of results, the follow<strong>in</strong>g econometric<br />

methods <strong>and</strong> the different middles proposed with their appropriate statistical test are discussed<br />

below.<br />

Empirical efforts of panel data often <strong>in</strong>volves choos<strong>in</strong>g between either runn<strong>in</strong>g the with<strong>in</strong><br />

or squares dummy variables (called fixed effects model) on the one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> the generalized<br />

feasible (also called r<strong>and</strong>om effects). To decide on which model to run, the Hausman test was<br />

used.The test specifies a null hypothesis, that, the preferred model is r<strong>and</strong>om effects. And the<br />

alternative is that the fixed effects model is preferred. To test this hypothesis <strong>in</strong> STATA, one<br />

runs the „xtreg‟ model with an option of fixed effects (fe) <strong>and</strong> stores its estimates. Further, the<br />

„xtreg‟ model, this time, with the r<strong>and</strong>om effects (re) option is run <strong>and</strong> the estimates are stored<br />

too. The program is then prompted to run the Hausman test. If the P-Value (or prob>chi2) is less<br />

than 0.05 (significant), then reject the null <strong>and</strong> conclude that the fixed effects models is more<br />

appropriate.<br />

However, before conclud<strong>in</strong>g that the r<strong>and</strong>om effects or fixed effects models are clearly<br />

appropriate, one has to test whether runn<strong>in</strong>g either of these models is appropriate. To test for the<br />

appropriateness of runn<strong>in</strong>g the r<strong>and</strong>om effects model, the Breusch – Pagan Lanagrange<br />

Multiplier (LM) test is used. It tests the null hypothesis that the variances across entities is zero<br />

or that there are no significant difference across units. And Stata‟s xttest0 is run immediately<br />

after runn<strong>in</strong>g an „xtreg‟ regression with the option of r<strong>and</strong>om effects. And if the P-Value (or<br />

prob> chi2) is less than 0.05 (significant), reject the null <strong>and</strong> conclude that the r<strong>and</strong>om effects<br />

model is appropriate. Otherwise, do not or fail to reject the null <strong>and</strong> conclude the r<strong>and</strong>om effects<br />

model is not appropriate. This is because there is no significant difference across entities or<br />

countries <strong>in</strong> this study.<br />

For the appropriateness of the fixed effects model, one tests for the pert<strong>in</strong>ence of both the<br />

time fixed effects <strong>and</strong> other fixed effects, such as the country fixed effects. In Stata, one uses the<br />

„testparm‟ (us<strong>in</strong>g „testprarm _Iyear‟) syntax to achieve this after runn<strong>in</strong>g the fixed effects with<br />

„i.year‟ <strong>in</strong>clusion, which generates time dummies. It tests the hypothesis that the jo<strong>in</strong>t time<br />

dummies are equal to zero. If the probability of F is less than 0.05, then it is significant <strong>and</strong><br />

conclude the jo<strong>in</strong>t time dummies are equal to zero <strong>and</strong> as such that it is appropriate to use the<br />

time fixed effects. Otherwise, no time fixed effects is needed if the statistics is <strong>in</strong>significant. And<br />

to test for entity fixed effects, say country fixed effects, one runs the „xi: reg‟ regression with<br />

„i.country‟ to generate country dummies that are then tested. One uses the „test‟ for the country<br />

dummies generated. It tests the null hypothesis that the entities are jo<strong>in</strong>tly equal to zero. And if<br />

54


the Prob> F is less than zero, it is significant <strong>and</strong> we reject the null <strong>and</strong> conclude that the fixed<br />

effects model is needed for that dataset.<br />

Methodologically, the study follows the <strong>in</strong>corporation of the country fixed effects like<br />

Anderson <strong>and</strong> Van W<strong>in</strong>coop (2003) <strong>in</strong> order to estimate a gravity model more grounded <strong>in</strong><br />

theory. And on econometric grounds, the study took cognizance of the asymmetries across<br />

sectors <strong>and</strong> country. This consideration provides robust results of the gravity model, like <strong>in</strong><br />

Subramanian <strong>and</strong> Wei, 2003.<br />

However, if the results, that are generated from this process are not plausible, a least<br />

squares methods to estimate the most consistent <strong>and</strong> reliable model that spells out the attributes<br />

of <strong>in</strong>terest is adopted.The other models are ML r<strong>and</strong>om effects, population-averaged model <strong>and</strong><br />

between effects models.<br />

4.5 Type <strong>and</strong> Sources of Data<br />

Gravity model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> its estimations require data on bilateral aggregate trade, <strong>in</strong>comes,<br />

population, distance, as well as geographical, cultural, <strong>and</strong> historical <strong>in</strong>formation. The study uses<br />

a panel data set cover<strong>in</strong>g five (5) products (see appendix A Table 4.2) <strong>and</strong> one hundred sixty<br />

eight (168) importers who have <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g their trade with the five (5) EAC countries (<strong>in</strong> the<br />

study called exporters). The list of countries (Exporters <strong>and</strong> Importers) used <strong>in</strong> the sample is<br />

presented <strong>in</strong> Appendix - A Table 4.3 <strong>and</strong> 4.4 respectively. The importers are the members of the<br />

EAC community.<br />

The study used secondary data from three ma<strong>in</strong> sources(see table 4.1 above). The <strong>Trade</strong><br />

data was picked from the UNCOMTRADE – WITS data base. The trade data is unidirectional,<br />

that is, exports of EAC member states to the ROW. The use of the unidirectional (or imports of j<br />

from i) trade volume as the regress<strong>and</strong> (Subramanian <strong>and</strong> Wei (2003)) are due to: the fact that,<br />

theoretical specifications of gravity-like models yield predictions on unidirectional trade rather<br />

than total trade; secondly, the trade effects of trade liberalizations (such as WTO, GSP etc.) are<br />

closely related to imports rather than exports. The logic is simple, if country j liberalizes through<br />

a certa<strong>in</strong> scheme like WTO or GSP with country i, it is expected that its imports from i would<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease. However, there is no valid theoretical argument for its exports to exp<strong>and</strong> by the same<br />

proportion even if the Abba Learner Symmetry holds; Abba Learner Symmetry states that the<br />

removal of import barriers serves to raise exports as well as imports. The symmetry would hold<br />

at the country‟s aggregate trade level rather than at the bilateral trade level. And thirdly, the<br />

effect of a liberalization <strong>and</strong> elim<strong>in</strong>ation of export subsidies are ambiguous <strong>in</strong> theory, s<strong>in</strong>ce an<br />

elim<strong>in</strong>ation of exports subsidies tends to reduces exports.<br />

The second component of the data was m<strong>in</strong>ed from the most current Penn World Tables<br />

7.0 (PWT 7.0). The Penn World Table (PWT) displays a set of national accounts economic time<br />

55


series cover<strong>in</strong>g many countries. Its expenditure entries are denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> a common set of<br />

prices <strong>in</strong> a common currency so that real quantity comparisons can be made, both between<br />

countries <strong>and</strong> over time. It also provides <strong>in</strong>formation about relative prices with<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> between<br />

countries, as well as demographic data <strong>and</strong> capital stock estimates. From this table, I downloaded<br />

data on the follow<strong>in</strong>g variables; Population (<strong>in</strong> thous<strong>and</strong>s), Exchange Rate, Real Gross Domestic<br />

Product per Capita, current price, Price Level of Gross Domestic Product, Openness <strong>in</strong> Current<br />

Prices, Real GDP per capita (Constant Prices: Laspeyres), derived from growth rates of c, g, I,<br />

Openness <strong>in</strong> Constant Prices, <strong>and</strong> years for the period.<br />

The third component of the data, was m<strong>in</strong>ed the from CEPII database. The data <strong>in</strong> this<br />

database relates to countries <strong>and</strong> their ma<strong>in</strong> city or agglomeration. Among the country-level<br />

variables are the first 3 identification codes of the country accord<strong>in</strong>g to the ISO classification, the<br />

country‟s area <strong>in</strong> square kilometers, used to calculate, <strong>in</strong> particular, its <strong>in</strong>ternal distance.<br />

Variables <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g whether the country is l<strong>and</strong>locked <strong>and</strong> which cont<strong>in</strong>ent it is part of are also<br />

<strong>in</strong>cluded. Also, I picked several language variables to proxy for <strong>in</strong>dexes of language proximity<br />

or dummy variables for common language <strong>in</strong> dyadic applications like gravity equations. The<br />

sources for all language <strong>in</strong>formation are the web site www.ethnologue.org <strong>and</strong> the CIA World<br />

Fact book. For each country, a report of the official languages (up to three), as well as the<br />

languages spoken by at least 20 percent of the population <strong>and</strong> the languages spoken by between 9<br />

<strong>and</strong> 20 percent of the population (up to four languages <strong>in</strong> each of those cases) was m<strong>in</strong>ed.<br />

Colonial l<strong>in</strong>kage variables which were used are also often used by economists to proxy for<br />

similarities <strong>in</strong> cultural, political or legal <strong>in</strong>stitutions. Our dataset provides several variables<br />

(based on the CIA World Fact book, <strong>and</strong> the Correlates of War Project run by political scientists,<br />

available at cow2.la.psu.edu) that identify for each country, up to 4 long-term <strong>and</strong> up to 3 shortterm<br />

colonizers <strong>in</strong> the whole history of the country.<br />

56


Chapter Five<br />

5.0 Presentation <strong>and</strong> Discussion of Empirical Results<br />

5.1 Introduction<br />

In this Chapter, the results <strong>and</strong> their discussions are undertaken. The first part of the section is<br />

devoted to presentation <strong>and</strong> discussion of the descriptive statistics. The aim was to exam<strong>in</strong>e the<br />

variables used <strong>in</strong> the model for possible errors. The second section discusses the diagnostic test.<br />

Specifically, the diagnostic tests were done to f<strong>in</strong>d out whether the <strong>in</strong>dependent variables were<br />

not perfectly multicoll<strong>in</strong>ear <strong>and</strong> whether the residuals were homoskedastic. The third section was<br />

devoted to the presentation <strong>and</strong> discussion of model estimates at the EAC level. The major aim<br />

was to determ<strong>in</strong>e which covariates <strong>in</strong>fluences EAC trade, estimate the size <strong>and</strong> magnitude of<br />

EAC dummy <strong>and</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d whether it creates or diverts trade, <strong>and</strong> also determ<strong>in</strong>e the sectoral patterns<br />

of EAC trade with food or agrifood products as the reference or base category.<br />

The next section is devoted to the discussion of estimates of the <strong>in</strong>dividual countries of<br />

EAC. Specifically, the issues that were presented <strong>and</strong> discussed at the bloc level are discussed<br />

for each country. This was made possible by extract<strong>in</strong>g each country‟s unique dataset from the<br />

major database created. The f<strong>in</strong>al section is devoted to discuss<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> present<strong>in</strong>g the summary of<br />

the empirical f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs.<br />

57


5.2 Descriptive Statistics<br />

For any plausible study to be mean<strong>in</strong>gful <strong>and</strong> the estimated model to have robust estimates it<br />

shouldbeg<strong>in</strong> by the description of the data <strong>and</strong> the estimated model adopted for the study. The<br />

description of the model relates to whether the covariates expla<strong>in</strong> well the flow <strong>in</strong> exports. And<br />

the description of the data relates to f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g out whether data is contam<strong>in</strong>ated with outliers <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>fluential variables. Where they were detected,they were treated as shown <strong>in</strong> the subsequent<br />

sections.<br />

5.2.1 Summary Statistics<br />

In this section, the summary statistics are presented <strong>and</strong> discussed. In the study, a number of<br />

covariates were used. However, Table 5.1 below presents the summary statistics for the major<br />

covariates used <strong>in</strong> the study;<br />

Table 5.1 Summary Statistics for Covariates used <strong>in</strong> the study<br />

Variable (<strong>in</strong> logs) Observations Mean St<strong>and</strong>ard Deviation M<strong>in</strong> Max<br />

Value of Exports (USD Current Prices) 3900 6001 2925.633 2.0 13562.7<br />

Importer Population 3900 9410.54 1781.818 3.66374 14.0959<br />

Exporter Population 3900 10448.9 77.3183 10.3257 10.5714<br />

Importer GDP (Current Prices) 3900 11385.7 2073.464 5.98829 16.4806<br />

Importer GDP Per Capita (Current Prices) 3900 8882.91 1437.536 5.05067 11.7706<br />

Exporter GDP (Current Prices) 3900 10613.2 193.1011 10.3375 10.91<br />

Exporter GDP Per Capita (Current Prices) 3900 7072.1 116.9586 6.91954 7.24637<br />

Source: Data used is from UN COMTRADE<br />

From table 5.1 above, average annual trade value is about 6,000 <strong>in</strong>thous<strong>and</strong>s of USD <strong>and</strong> this<br />

value could range between 2 thous<strong>and</strong> of USD <strong>and</strong> 14,000of thous<strong>and</strong>s of USD. The average<br />

population of the export<strong>in</strong>g countries of EAC is almost ten times theaverage population of the<br />

import<strong>in</strong>g countries <strong>in</strong> the rest of the world. On average EAC has a population of about10,<br />

500,000while the ROW has only 1,000,000 persons on average.The average nom<strong>in</strong>al GDP <strong>and</strong><br />

GDP per capita of the import<strong>in</strong>g countries is more than 1,000,000 than that of the export<strong>in</strong>g EAC<br />

countries. The average GDP of EAC is 10, 603, 2000 <strong>and</strong> that of the ROW is 11, 385,700. While<br />

the per capita GDP is of EAC is 8,882,910 <strong>and</strong> the one for the ROW is 11,448,900 on average.<br />

58


5.2.2 Regression Correlation Matrix<br />

In order to f<strong>in</strong>d out the degree of l<strong>in</strong>ear relationship between the dependent variable (log of<br />

exports) <strong>and</strong> its covariates, a tabulationof the PearsonCorrelation Matric was done. Table 5.2<br />

below presents the correlation matrix for all the variables used <strong>in</strong> the model at the 0.05 level of<br />

significance.<br />

Table 5.2 Show<strong>in</strong>g Correlation of Selected Covariates of the Study<br />

LExports<strong>in</strong>~d 1.0000<br />

Lexporterpop 1.0000<br />

lexporterx~t -0.4209* 1.0000<br />

0.0000<br />

.<br />

LExpor~d Ldist Li~tcgdp Li~rcgdp Le~rcgdp Lexpor~l Limpo~op<br />

Ldist -0.1789* 1.0000<br />

0.0000<br />

Limportert~p 0.3926* 0.4948* 1.0000<br />

0.0000 0.0000<br />

Limporterc~p 0.0683* 0.6186* 0.5353* 1.0000<br />

0.0000 0.0000 0.0000<br />

Lexporterc~p 0.0729* 0.0175 0.0894* 0.1191* 1.0000<br />

0.0000 0.2733 0.0000 0.0000<br />

Lexporterr~l 0.0671* 0.0182 0.0801* 0.1151* 0.9576* 1.0000<br />

0.0000 0.2548 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000<br />

Limporterpop 0.4018* 0.0767* 0.7318* -0.1839* 0.0079 0.0003 1.0000<br />

0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.6202 0.9835<br />

Lexporterpop 0.0728* 0.0153 0.0874* 0.1149* 0.9748* 0.9102* 0.0090<br />

0.0000 0.3386 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.5757<br />

lexporterx~t -0.0295 -0.0133 -0.0381* -0.0663* -0.5716* -0.7230* 0.0091<br />

0.0652 0.4062 0.0172 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.5702<br />

Lexpo~op lexpor~t<br />

The numbers <strong>in</strong> the table are Pearson Correlation Coefficients <strong>and</strong> move from positive 1<br />

(imply<strong>in</strong>g a strong correlation) to negative 1 (imply<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>verse relationship). All the variables<br />

are correlated with LExports <strong>in</strong> 1000s of USDs s<strong>in</strong>ce they are all significant. The log of distance<br />

<strong>and</strong> exchange rate of the exporter are negative correlated to the LExports as expected from<br />

theory. All the other variables have the expected signs of correlation to LExports. For a graphical<br />

presentation of this correlation matrix <strong>in</strong> a series of scatter plots for all the variables, see figure<br />

5.1 <strong>in</strong> appendix B. Visually all the variables are clustered together. This implies that the<br />

covariates have a relation with the <strong>in</strong>dependent variable.<br />

59


5.2.3 Assessment of the Model Us<strong>in</strong>g the Observed Versus Predicted Values<br />

Another issues to consider before estimat<strong>in</strong>g the model, is to f<strong>in</strong>d out whether the predicted or<br />

specified model‟s covariates predict the dependent variable (Lexports) well. To conclude on how<br />

well or good the model can predict the flow of exports, one looks at the relationship of l<strong>in</strong>earity<br />

of the model <strong>and</strong> the behavior of its residuals.A graphic of this relationship is presented <strong>in</strong> Figure<br />

5.2 below;<br />

Figure 5.2 Regression Results of Observed Aga<strong>in</strong>st Predicted Values<br />

10 15<br />

0 5<br />

-5 0 5 10 15<br />

LExports<strong>in</strong>1000usd predicted<br />

A visual <strong>in</strong>spection of the above figure <strong>in</strong>dicates or showsthe scatter produc<strong>in</strong>g a cluster of the<br />

relationship between the observed <strong>and</strong> the predicted values at a 45 degree pattern of the dataset.<br />

Because of this pattern, the model does a good job <strong>in</strong> predict<strong>in</strong>g the exports of EAC.<br />

5.2.4 Test for Normality<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ce this study used ord<strong>in</strong>ary least squares to predict <strong>and</strong> produce its estimates, a normality test<br />

of the residuals was done. When the residuals are not normally distributed, the validity of the ttest,<br />

p-values <strong>and</strong> F-test will all be <strong>in</strong>fluenced. To achieve or conclude on this, a kernel density<br />

for a graphic <strong>in</strong>terpretation (See figure 5.3 below) <strong>and</strong> the Shapiro-Wilk test for normality were<br />

applied. For the Shapiro-Wilk test, a null hypothesis that the distribution of the errors is normally<br />

distributed is prescribed. When the statistic is significant, we reject the null that the errors are<br />

60


Density<br />

normally distributed. In this study, Shapiro-Wilk test produces a significant statistic(with Prob><br />

Z = 0) s<strong>in</strong>ce it is less than 0.05, hence the null hypothesis that the data is normal or comes from a<br />

normal population is rejected. The Kernel density <strong>in</strong> Figure 5.3 below shows that the probability<br />

density distribution <strong>and</strong> the outlay of the residuals not almost perfectly match<strong>in</strong>g the normal<br />

distribution outlay. When this is so, one concludes that the data is not normally distributed.<br />

Table 5.3 Shapiro-Wilk W test for Normal Data<br />

Variable Observations W V z Prob>z<br />

e 3900 0.9909 19.8 7.77 0<br />

Figure 5.3 Show<strong>in</strong>g the Kernel Density Plot with an overlay of a Normal Distribution<br />

.1 .2 .3<br />

0<br />

0 5 10 15<br />

L<strong>in</strong>ear prediction<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>in</strong> Figure 5.3 above, show<strong>in</strong>g the kernel density plot not fitt<strong>in</strong>g the normal distribution plot<br />

perfectly, <strong>and</strong> Shapiro-Wilk test statistic be<strong>in</strong>g significant,it implies that estimates of the pvalues,<br />

t-tests <strong>and</strong> f-test would not be valid <strong>and</strong> are even <strong>in</strong>fluenced. To overcome this problem,<br />

the dataset was transformed. The choice of the transformation was partly determ<strong>in</strong>ed from theory<br />

<strong>and</strong> the use of the gladder comm<strong>and</strong>s of STATA.<br />

61


5.3 Regression Diagnostics<br />

Hav<strong>in</strong>g determ<strong>in</strong>ed, from the descriptive section, that the data, variables <strong>and</strong> model are processes<br />

well-structured (or where they were not, they were corrected to be well structured),<strong>and</strong> that they<br />

behaved well <strong>in</strong> their relationship to each other <strong>and</strong> the dependent variable exports, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong><br />

predict<strong>in</strong>g the model, the study then did diagnostics test. The specific diagnostic testof Breush –<br />

Pegan for homoscedasticity <strong>and</strong> Wooldridge test for autocorrelation were done to check for <strong>and</strong><br />

treat for heteroscadacity. The other diagnostic testrelated to f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g out if the variables suffer<br />

from perfect multicoll<strong>in</strong>earity or whether the errors are collated.Whenever the data suffered from<br />

these problems, then a solution for them wassought first before runn<strong>in</strong>g regressions. When<br />

variables are perfectly coll<strong>in</strong>ear, then it is impossible to determ<strong>in</strong>e the determ<strong>in</strong>ant of the matrix<br />

used <strong>in</strong> transform<strong>in</strong>g the variables, so as to assist <strong>in</strong> produc<strong>in</strong>g the estimates. Andthe variables<br />

are autocorrelated, the estimates generated are <strong>in</strong>valid s<strong>in</strong>ce the t-values <strong>and</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard errors are<br />

not precise <strong>and</strong> efficient. If, the dataset does not suffer any of these or the problems have been<br />

accounted for, then the dataset <strong>and</strong> model may be used to estimate the results.<br />

5.3.1 Test<strong>in</strong>g for Homoscedasticity<br />

In runn<strong>in</strong>g the regressions, therewasan important assumption that the variances of the residuals<br />

are constant or „homoskedastic‟. To determ<strong>in</strong>e if this is so, a graphical method was<br />

used.STATA‟s “rvfplot” <strong>in</strong>built comm<strong>and</strong> was used to plot the graphical that helped <strong>in</strong> check<strong>in</strong>g<br />

for homoskedascity. To reaffirm the graphical plot results, theBreusch-Pagan test was employed.<br />

However, without delv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to the <strong>in</strong>tricacies of these approaches, Stock <strong>and</strong> Watson 2003, notes<br />

that, „asa rule of thumb, always assumeshomoscedasticity <strong>in</strong> your model‟.Silva <strong>and</strong> Tenreyo,<br />

2006, also allude to such a conclusion when they make mention of the fact that the null<br />

hypothesis that there is homoscedasticity is rejected <strong>in</strong> traditional fixed-effects gravity equations.<br />

As such, this study presumed that the data suffered from heteroskedasticity. As, the study<br />

predicted that the gravity model may provide wrong estimates of the st<strong>and</strong>ard errors of the<br />

coefficients coupled with wrong t-values. S<strong>in</strong>ce the results were estimated us<strong>in</strong>g STATA, one<br />

needs only to adjust the model by <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g the robust (re) option to the model to overcome<br />

this problem <strong>and</strong> improve the estimates of the regressions.<br />

62


5.3.2 Test<strong>in</strong>g for Multicoll<strong>in</strong>earity<br />

Another important assumption is that the <strong>in</strong>dependent variables should not be perfectly 23 l<strong>in</strong>ear<br />

functions of each other. If they are, then it is not possible to f<strong>in</strong>d their determ<strong>in</strong>ants <strong>and</strong> hence<br />

solutions to a model. However, <strong>in</strong> STATA, when variables are perfectly coll<strong>in</strong>ear, they are<br />

dropped automatically from the estimates. For example, the log of exporter GDP <strong>and</strong> GDP per<br />

capita variable has been consistently coll<strong>in</strong>ear <strong>in</strong> all regressions run. The current colony estimate<br />

was also coll<strong>in</strong>ear <strong>in</strong> all estimates. This is probably due to the fact that, there is no EAC member<br />

state that is <strong>in</strong> a current colonial relationship, hence the dummy variable‟s determ<strong>in</strong>ant is not<br />

def<strong>in</strong>ed to help <strong>in</strong> the evaluation process of the estimate – caus<strong>in</strong>g the problem of perfect<br />

coll<strong>in</strong>earity. As such, the variables were dropped from the estimation process by the statistical<br />

program.<br />

The study also employed or used the Wooldridge test for autocorrelation <strong>in</strong> panel-data<br />

models 24 . The test specifies a null hypothesis that there is no first order autocorrelation. When<br />

the test statistic is significant, then there is serial correlation. In Table 5.4 below, the Wooldridge<br />

test statistic is significant s<strong>in</strong>ce its P-value is 0.000. And s<strong>in</strong>ce this is less than 0.05, it implies<br />

that the null hypothesis is rejected. Hence, there is serial correlation or the model suffers from<br />

serial correlation.<br />

Table 5.4 Wooldridge test for autocorrelation <strong>in</strong> panel data<br />

H0: no first order autocorrelation<br />

F( 1, 421) = 47.661<br />

Prob> F = 0.0000<br />

Follow<strong>in</strong>g Gurati, 2004, the study ignored the problem of coll<strong>in</strong>earity s<strong>in</strong>ce it does not seem to<br />

be serious <strong>and</strong> affect<strong>in</strong>g the variables of <strong>in</strong>terest. Only three variables were coll<strong>in</strong>ear <strong>and</strong> the<br />

explanation for this was established.<br />

23<br />

One may ignore this problem if the regressors are not perfectly coll<strong>in</strong>ear. This follows the “do noth<strong>in</strong>g‟ wisdom of<br />

Gujarati, 2004.<br />

24<br />

Wooldridge, J. M. 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section <strong>and</strong> Panel Data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press 282-<br />

283).<br />

63


5.4 Presentation of Estimates <strong>and</strong> Discussion of Results<br />

In this sub-section, the presentation of the estimates <strong>and</strong> the results from the study are discussed<br />

<strong>in</strong> relation to the objectives specified earlier on. More to this, a discussion <strong>and</strong> summary of the<br />

econometrics methods <strong>and</strong> approach were done <strong>in</strong> sub-section 5.4.1. In the subsequent subsections,<br />

the objectives <strong>and</strong> results estimated for EAC as a bloc <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dividual countries is<br />

discussed. The first objective, discussed <strong>in</strong> sub-section 5.4.2, relates to the evaluation of the<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>ants of EAC export trade. In the next sub-section, 5.4.3, a presentation <strong>and</strong> discussion of<br />

the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs relat<strong>in</strong>g to the sectoral impact of the selected sector (agricultural raw materials,<br />

fuels, ores <strong>and</strong> metals <strong>and</strong> the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector) is undertaken. The base sector or reference<br />

category is the food item sector. The presentation of the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> discussion of EAC regional<br />

trade agreement is done <strong>in</strong> sub-section 5.4.4.<br />

5.4.1 Summary of Econometrics Methods<br />

In the estimation of results, the follow<strong>in</strong>g steps were followed with the justifications here<strong>in</strong>.<br />

Results relat<strong>in</strong>g to the EAC Bloc are tabulated <strong>in</strong> Tables 5.5 <strong>and</strong> that of the EAC countries is <strong>in</strong><br />

table 5.6 <strong>and</strong> 5.7<strong>in</strong> Appendix C. The tables formally detail the econometric methods <strong>and</strong> the<br />

different models run with their appropriate statistical tests.<br />

Empirical efforts of panel data often <strong>in</strong>volves choos<strong>in</strong>g between either runn<strong>in</strong>g the with<strong>in</strong><br />

or squares dummy variables (called fixed effects model) on the one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> the generalized<br />

feasible (also called r<strong>and</strong>om effects). In this regard, a Hausman test was executed to decide on<br />

the appropriateness of the model to run. The Hausman test specifies a null hypothesis that the<br />

preferred model is r<strong>and</strong>om effects. While the alternative is that the fixed effects model is<br />

preferred. To achieve this, afixed effects model i.e. run the „xtreg‟ model with an option of fixed<br />

effects (fe) was specified <strong>and</strong> run with the resultsof the estimatesstored.Then a r<strong>and</strong>om effects<br />

model was also run (i.erun the „xtreg‟ model with a r<strong>and</strong>om effects (re) option <strong>and</strong> store the<br />

estimates). On specify<strong>in</strong>g the Hausman test, it revealed a chi-2(15) = 235.72, which is highly<br />

significant at all levels. Because of this f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g, the null hypothesis is rejected that the preferred<br />

model is r<strong>and</strong>om effects model. Hence the study employs the fixed-effects model.<br />

The next econometric issue to consider was what type of fixed effects model to run <strong>and</strong><br />

what estimation model to estimate. One could run the one-way, two-way <strong>and</strong> three-way fixed<br />

effects models. The choice of which at best, could partially depend on the data type <strong>and</strong> it size.<br />

<strong>Trade</strong> data suffersfrom the problem of heterogeneity. S<strong>in</strong>ce heterogeneity was deemed <strong>and</strong><br />

observed <strong>in</strong> the country pairs <strong>in</strong> the dataset, estimat<strong>in</strong>g a gravity model <strong>in</strong> panel elim<strong>in</strong>ated this<br />

problem (follow<strong>in</strong>g Westerlund <strong>and</strong> Wilhelmsson, 2006 conclusions). However, this would not<br />

elim<strong>in</strong>ate all the heterogeneity <strong>in</strong> the trade data, especially emanat<strong>in</strong>g from the nature of the<br />

64


covariates. The study also took cognizance that estimates of the gravity model generated from a<br />

log-l<strong>in</strong>ear form us<strong>in</strong>g OLSare <strong>in</strong>efficient <strong>and</strong> not precise, i.e. they are biased <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>efficient as<br />

Westerlund <strong>and</strong> Wilhelmsson, 2006 25 allude to <strong>and</strong> are not theoretically founded.Another issue<br />

confront<strong>in</strong>g trade data <strong>and</strong> analysis is the presence of zero trade data which could be the result of<br />

no trade, measurement errors or round<strong>in</strong>g errors. S<strong>in</strong>ce trade data is normally <strong>in</strong> thous<strong>and</strong>s of<br />

USD, the values which are less than half of this are rounded to zero 26 , thus make estimate over-<br />

or –under estimated. To overcome this problem, the exports were measured not <strong>in</strong> thous<strong>and</strong>s of<br />

USD but <strong>in</strong> their multiplicative form 27 . Care was taken to avoid miss<strong>in</strong>g values.Where they<br />

existed; they were compensated for by exports,s<strong>in</strong>ce the imports were the primary source of the<br />

trade data 28 . And where the miss<strong>in</strong>g values still existed, they were considered to be true zero<br />

trade 29 .<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ce the traditional econometric method of estimat<strong>in</strong>g a gravity model <strong>in</strong> log-l<strong>in</strong>earized<br />

form produces results that are not precise <strong>and</strong> efficient, the quest was to estimate a gravity model<br />

with a technique that h<strong>and</strong>les the problem of zero trade data, solves the heterogeneity problem<br />

<strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> trade data, <strong>and</strong> is theoretically grounded. One of the only two theoretically grounded<br />

gravity estimation techniques 30 , is to use the Poisson fixed effects estimator (pseudo Maximum<br />

Likelihood (ML) technique) <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with Silva <strong>and</strong> Tenreyro, 2006; <strong>and</strong> Westerlund <strong>and</strong><br />

Wilhelmsson, 2006). The Poisson estimation wasdonewith exports (the dependent variable) <strong>in</strong> it<br />

multiplicative form or orig<strong>in</strong>al formulation not <strong>in</strong> a log-l<strong>in</strong>earized form. The model was then<br />

estimated us<strong>in</strong>g OLS, produc<strong>in</strong>g betterresults that were not as biased <strong>and</strong> efficient estimates as<br />

25<br />

They state that biases <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>efficiencies emanat<strong>in</strong>g from heteroskedasticity have been ignored <strong>in</strong> empirical work.<br />

26<br />

The upward round<strong>in</strong>g off could cancel the effect of downward round<strong>in</strong>g off <strong>and</strong> does not pose any problem.<br />

However, if your dataset <strong>in</strong>cluded country pairs that are distant <strong>and</strong> even small this may not be plausible.<br />

27<br />

To generate exports, the study employed the multiplicative form i.e. Exports = Exports<strong>in</strong>1000USD*1000 to<br />

generate an <strong>in</strong>teger.<br />

28<br />

The imports were compensated or <strong>in</strong>flated by 10 percent (on average this is equal to CIF/FOB=1.1). However,<br />

there was also a pre-selection of the importers <strong>and</strong> exports used. Only exporters who had all the trade data for the<br />

period were considered.<br />

29<br />

When zero trade values still exist after these transformations <strong>and</strong> considerations, it should not be a problem when<br />

they are r<strong>and</strong>om. Nevertheless, this is not always the case. However, a serious problem will be encountered when<br />

the zero is <strong>in</strong> the dependent variable when the gravity model is estimated <strong>in</strong> it multiplicative form. Nonetheless, the<br />

gravity model (even <strong>in</strong> its log-l<strong>in</strong>ear form 29 ) can still be estimated with such challenges (Silva <strong>and</strong> Tenreyro 2006 &<br />

Frankel). And the challenges, especially of log-l<strong>in</strong>earization, are even escalated <strong>in</strong> the presence of<br />

heteroskedasticity. As such, the estimates of the log-l<strong>in</strong>earized gravity model are noted to be biased <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>efficient<br />

<strong>and</strong> should not be used to <strong>in</strong>fer trade dynamics. The traditional estimation of the gravity model <strong>in</strong>volve one logl<strong>in</strong>eariz<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the model first <strong>and</strong> then estimat<strong>in</strong>g it with fixed-effects (Westerlund <strong>and</strong> Wilhelmsson, 2006). However,<br />

<strong>in</strong> the presence of heteroskedascity, the results of the OLS are biased <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>efficient. Further, the log-l<strong>in</strong>earized<br />

models truncate the negative trade <strong>and</strong> zero trade, or even some empirical the negative <strong>and</strong> zero trade are<br />

compensated for with a positive value. However, this <strong>in</strong>troduces another problem of selection bias. There seems not<br />

to be a solution yet to h<strong>and</strong>le zero trade however.<br />

30<br />

The other one <strong>in</strong>volves us<strong>in</strong>g the two stage estimation technique developed by Helpman et al, 2007 that is<br />

identical to the sample selection bias. In the first stage, it <strong>in</strong>volves f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g the likelihood or probability that two<br />

countries trade with each other us<strong>in</strong>g the probit. This enables one to estimate the mills ratio. In the second stage, s<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the mills ratio from stage one that controls for the bias <strong>in</strong> sample selection, <strong>and</strong> hence control for firm heterogeneity,<br />

<strong>and</strong> estimate the gravity equation <strong>in</strong> levels us<strong>in</strong>g the Heckman estimation technique.<br />

65


those of the log-l<strong>in</strong>earized gravity model. This is because the estimation procedure is done for<br />

zero trade, s<strong>in</strong>ce the dependent variable is <strong>in</strong> level <strong>and</strong> it has no requirement for it to be an<br />

<strong>in</strong>teger. The data was not Poisson distributed (Westerlund <strong>and</strong> Wilhelmsson, 2006). Therefore<br />

the Poisson fixed effects model, an appropriate estimation technique, was employed <strong>in</strong><br />

estimat<strong>in</strong>g the gravity model. The estimates of this process are shown <strong>in</strong> table 5.5 31 <strong>in</strong> appendix<br />

C. Column one of table 5.5 shows results for the EAC bloc <strong>and</strong> the subsequent columns show the<br />

results for Burundi, Kenya, Rw<strong>and</strong>a, Tanzania <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a respectively. The results for logl<strong>in</strong>earized<br />

form are also produced <strong>and</strong> may be found <strong>in</strong> tables 5.6 <strong>and</strong> 5.7 <strong>in</strong> appendix C too.<br />

5.4.2 Results of the Determ<strong>in</strong>ants of Exports of EAC<br />

One set of objectives of this study was to estimate the effect of the adopted trade liberalization<br />

policy, determ<strong>in</strong>e <strong>and</strong> estimate which covariates expla<strong>in</strong> bloc trade at both the regional <strong>and</strong><br />

country levels. Hav<strong>in</strong>g considered all the necessary econometric issues, a set of two equations<br />

were run <strong>and</strong> estimated.<br />

Of the traditional gravity model covariates, the coefficients of distance, both theimporter<br />

GDP <strong>and</strong> GDP per capita , shar<strong>in</strong>g a common border, shar<strong>in</strong>g official <strong>and</strong> ethnographic language,<br />

ever be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a colonial relationship <strong>and</strong> the trad<strong>in</strong>g country-pair ever be<strong>in</strong>g same countryhad<br />

positive <strong>and</strong> significant<strong>in</strong>fluences on trade. These <strong>and</strong> other covariates wereall significant at 1<br />

percent level <strong>and</strong> have the right signs theoretically, <strong>and</strong> as such, they determ<strong>in</strong>e the exports of<br />

EAC. For example, ceteris peribus, when there is a percentage change <strong>in</strong> distance, the exports of<br />

EAC decrease by 0.01. The impact is much smaller than the estimates generated by traditional<br />

OLS estimations of the gravity modewhich is 1.12 (see table 5.6). However, EAC bloc exports<br />

go<strong>in</strong>g to a country shar<strong>in</strong>g the same official language enhanced trade more than otherwise. This<br />

is because shar<strong>in</strong>g a common official language enhances trade by 43 percent on average,more<br />

than the benchmark of export<strong>in</strong>g to a country that does not share this same language. However,<br />

EAC performance of exports go<strong>in</strong>g to a country shar<strong>in</strong>g a common ethnographic language is not<br />

enhanced morethan the benchmark. That is, shar<strong>in</strong>g a common ethnographic performs less than<br />

not shar<strong>in</strong>g a common ethnographic by an average of 52 percent.These f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs seem to be <strong>in</strong><br />

l<strong>in</strong>e with Silva <strong>and</strong> Tenreyro‟s f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs that distance <strong>and</strong> common language elasticities play a<br />

smaller role on trade for Poisson estimation than OLS estimations of the gravity model. The<br />

latter predicts an estimate on these variables closer to unity 32 .However, a percentage <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong><br />

both the importer GDP <strong>and</strong> GPD per capita <strong>in</strong>crease trade by 0.075 <strong>and</strong> 0.025 respectively. These<br />

31 The estimation results for EAC bloc were produced us<strong>in</strong>g thetwo-way Poisson fixed technique. The rest of the<br />

results were produced us<strong>in</strong>g the one-way Poisson fixed effects Poisson technique except for Ug<strong>and</strong>a which were<br />

estimated the one fixed effect <strong>in</strong> it log-l<strong>in</strong>earized form. This is because the results for Ug<strong>and</strong>a failed to converge.<br />

32 Carrere, 2004, quot<strong>in</strong>g Obstfeld <strong>and</strong> Rogoff, 2001, suggest a consensus that the coefficient of distance should be<br />

between -1.2 <strong>and</strong> -0.8, which is identical to what is estimated.<br />

66


estimates from ML estimations produce a greater effect on trade than those from OLS estimation<br />

techniques as asserted by Silva <strong>and</strong> Tenenyro, 2006. However, EAC exports go<strong>in</strong>g to countries<br />

that rema<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the same colonial relationship after 1945, or to countries that shares a common<br />

border with it, <strong>and</strong> exporters who were the same country with EAC bloc, on average <strong>in</strong>creased<br />

trade than otherwise by 331 percent, 163 percent <strong>and</strong> 129 percent respectively from the<br />

benchmarks.<br />

More to this, Burundi‟s exports are <strong>in</strong>fluenced by the choice of its importers‟ GDP size<br />

<strong>and</strong> the fact that it has been <strong>in</strong> a colonial relationship with the importer. Ceteris paribus, for every<br />

percentage <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the importer‟s GDP,Burundi‟s <strong>in</strong>crease exports by 0.0047. Burundi‟s<br />

exports are more enhanced when it exports to a country that has ever been <strong>in</strong> a colonial<br />

relationship with it than when it exports to one that has never been. This because, the colonial<br />

ties performs better than Burundi‟s exports go<strong>in</strong>g to a country that has never been <strong>in</strong> a colonial<br />

relationship by 654 percent on average. The colonial ties also has similar effects on Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s<br />

exports,i.e. when Ug<strong>and</strong>a exports to a country that has been <strong>in</strong> a colonial relation with it, its<br />

exports are more enhanced because the colonial ties perform better than otherwise <strong>and</strong> on<br />

average it is 200 percent better than Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s exports to country that has not ever been <strong>in</strong> a<br />

colonial l<strong>in</strong>k. The choice of the importer‟s GDP also <strong>in</strong>fluences the exports of the other EAC<br />

member countries, just as Burundi‟s. For <strong>in</strong>stance, for every percentage <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the<br />

importer‟s GDP, the exports of Kenya, Rw<strong>and</strong>a Tanzania <strong>in</strong>crease by 0.0078, 0.033 <strong>and</strong> 0.0082<br />

respectively. However, a percentage <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the importer‟s GDP <strong>in</strong>creases Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s exports<br />

by 0.92 (which is closer to unity as predicted by theory) 33 . Another determ<strong>in</strong>ant that seems to<br />

<strong>in</strong>fluence most of the exports of the exporters or EAC states is distance. And for every<br />

percentage change <strong>in</strong> distance per kilometer, the exports of Kenya, Rw<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong> reduce by<br />

0.0143, 0.013 <strong>and</strong> 0.01 respectively. Nevertheless, Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s percentage reduction <strong>in</strong> exports<br />

reduces by 1.06 for every percentage <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> distance.<br />

Kenya‟s exports are <strong>in</strong>fluenced by its own GDP, the GDP per capita of its importer, the<br />

contiguity of the importer of its products, the fact that its exports go to a country that shares the<br />

same official language with it, by the fact that it has ever been <strong>in</strong> a colonial relationship with the<br />

exporter <strong>and</strong> that they were the same country with the importer. For illustration, for every<br />

percentage <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the GDP per capita of the importer <strong>and</strong> GDP of Kenya, the exports of<br />

Kenya <strong>in</strong>crease by 0.005 <strong>and</strong> 0.12 respectively. But, when Kenya exports to a country it shares a<br />

border with, its exports are enhanced more than when it exports to one that is not <strong>in</strong> contiguity<br />

with it. This is because the contiguity out performs the lack of contiguity by 177 percent on<br />

average. Further, when Kenya exports go to a country that shares a common official language, it<br />

enhances trade more than when it exports to country that does not share this language. The<br />

reason be<strong>in</strong>g that, the common official language out performs the lack of it by 68 percent on<br />

33 Ibid<br />

67


average more than when it exports to a country that does not share a common official language.<br />

More to this, Kenya trad<strong>in</strong>g with a country that rema<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> a similar colonial relationship with it<br />

after 1945 out performs trad<strong>in</strong>g with a country that did not rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> such a relationship by 213<br />

percent on average. Exports of Kenya are more enhanced when they go to a country that was one<br />

<strong>and</strong> the same with it, s<strong>in</strong>ce same country with<strong>in</strong> the last 75 years performs better than otherwise.<br />

The exports of Rw<strong>and</strong>a are also <strong>in</strong>fluencedby contiguity of the importer of its product,<br />

i.e., contiguity enhances trade by 750 percent on average than not be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> contiguity for<br />

Rw<strong>and</strong>a. Further, Rw<strong>and</strong>an exports are more enhanced when they go to an importer who has<br />

ever been <strong>in</strong> the same colonial relation after 1945 (col45)than when they go to a country that did<br />

not follow this arrangement. The col45 variable exp<strong>and</strong>s trade over 542 percent on average than<br />

not have exports go to such a country.While the col45 for Tanzania estimate of 517 percent<br />

overage outperforms the exports to a country which did not rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> the same colonial relation<br />

after 1945. However, the common colonizer <strong>in</strong>dicator for Rw<strong>and</strong>a outperforms the exports to a<br />

non-common colonizer of Rw<strong>and</strong>a by 297 percent on average.<br />

5.4.3 Application to the assessment of the effects of regional trade agreements.<br />

Another objective related to f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g the impact of EAC bloc on exports – especially its <strong>in</strong>fluence<br />

on trade creation<strong>and</strong>trade diversion <strong>and</strong> also imputes the welfare implications of the trade<br />

liberalization policy of the EAC trade agreement.To capture this, dummies of <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc trade,<br />

bloc export <strong>and</strong> bloc imports were specified. Refer to table 5.6 for the estimates of these<br />

dummies. Inference is made for coefficients that are not only statistically significant, but also<br />

economically sensible.For EAC bloc, EAC_Exports <strong>and</strong> EAC_Intra dummies are significant.<br />

Follow<strong>in</strong>g the Westerlund <strong>and</strong> Wilhelmsson, 2006 <strong>in</strong>terpretation of these dummies, s<strong>in</strong>ce the<br />

EAC_<strong>in</strong>tra dummycoefficient is greater than zero (i.e. 0.05), it implies that the EAC bloc creates<br />

trade. EAC has created trade by 5 percenton average more than trade predicted by reference (it<br />

could be presumed to <strong>in</strong> substitution to domestically generated production). However, this<br />

statistic is lowerthan the 40 percent that is predicted fromPoisson estimations. This lower figure<br />

could be due to truncat<strong>in</strong>g EAC importer members (to avoid homogeneity issues) <strong>and</strong> the<br />

truncation of the products used for analysis. However, s<strong>in</strong>ce the coefficient of EAC_exports is<br />

less than zero (i.e. -0.21), then it is analogous to export diversion. This corresponds to export<br />

diversion of up to 19 percent on average. And follow<strong>in</strong>g Carrere, 2006, s<strong>in</strong>ce the EAC_Intra<br />

coefficient is positive <strong>and</strong> EAC_Exports coefficient is negative, this corresponds to pure trade<br />

diversion <strong>in</strong> terms of exports. This f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g can also be used to <strong>in</strong>fer on the welfare of the nonbloc<br />

members, i.e. the welfare of the non-members of EAC is reduc<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Kenya‟s membership <strong>in</strong> the EAC leads to trade creation s<strong>in</strong>ce the coefficient of<br />

EAC_<strong>in</strong>tra is positive (1.53). The trade that is created by Kenya‟s membership <strong>in</strong> EAC is about<br />

68


361 percent than if it was not a member of EAC. In Tanzania‟s <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s membership <strong>in</strong> the<br />

EAC however, seems to have reduced theirtrade creation effects s<strong>in</strong>ce the EAC dummy<br />

coefficients for Tanzania of -0.77 <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a of -1.63, are negative, than the basel<strong>in</strong>e. This<br />

corresponds to about 55 percent<strong>and</strong> 80 percent trade creation reduction on average than<br />

otherwise. Further, Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s bloc EAC_exports is positive 0.53. This corresponds to 70 percent<br />

average reductions <strong>in</strong> trade diversion than expla<strong>in</strong>ed otherwise. More to this, its estimate of<br />

EAC_imports <strong>and</strong> imports is positive 1.40. This corresponds to 306 percent analogous to<br />

reduction <strong>in</strong> imports diversion.<br />

5.4.3 Application to the sectoral assessment of the effects of the adopted sectors<br />

The other objective of this study was to estimate the impact of EAC on food item trade <strong>in</strong><br />

relation to the other sectors. A set of dummies captur<strong>in</strong>g the sectors or product aggregates was<br />

specified with food sector as the base dummy.<br />

The coefficient of the dummies for EAC sectoral trade <strong>in</strong> agricultural raw materials trade,<br />

fuels, ores <strong>and</strong> metals, <strong>and</strong> manufactures are -0.33, -0.60, -1.78 <strong>and</strong> -0.4 respectively. And s<strong>in</strong>ce<br />

they are all negative, it means that the exports of the food sector perform significantly better than<br />

all the other sectors. For example, the performance of agricultural raw material exports is lower<br />

than the exports from the food sector by 28 percent for the bloc. More to this, the agricultural<br />

raw materials sector performs also less than the food sector <strong>in</strong> the rest of the EAC member states<br />

except for Kenya <strong>and</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a where the performance of the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector is not<br />

significantly different from average contribution of the food sector on exports. The estimated<br />

coefficient for Burundi, Tanzania <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a are -1.59, -0.24 <strong>and</strong> -1.60 respectively. In terms of<br />

percentages, both Burundi‟s <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s performance of agricultural raw materials on exports<br />

areon average 80 percent less than the food sector. And Tanzania‟s agricultural raw materials<br />

average contribution on exports is 21 percent less than food sector‟s performance.<br />

The manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector estimates across all countries <strong>and</strong> EAC bloc outputs are all<br />

negative, imply<strong>in</strong>g that the sector performs worse than the food sector. However, the average<br />

performance of Kenya‟s manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector on exports is not significantly different to that of<br />

food sector. The coefficient for the bloc manufactur<strong>in</strong>g exports is -0.4, <strong>and</strong> that of Burundi,<br />

Rw<strong>and</strong>a, Tanzania <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a are -1.54, -1.87, -0.49 <strong>and</strong> -1.76 respectively. In percentage terms<br />

themanufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector performance is comparatively worse than the food sector by 32 percent<br />

for EAC bloc exports, 79 for Burundi, 85 percent for Rw<strong>and</strong>a, 39 percent for Tanzania <strong>and</strong> 83<br />

percent for Ug<strong>and</strong>a.On the average, Rw<strong>and</strong>a‟s fuel <strong>and</strong> ores <strong>and</strong> metals sectors perform worse<br />

than the food sector with coefficients of 2.61 <strong>and</strong> 0.45 respectively. In terms of percentages, the<br />

fuels <strong>and</strong> ores <strong>and</strong> metals sectors perform better than the food sector by 1250 percent <strong>and</strong> 57<br />

percent on average <strong>in</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a. The fuels sector of EAC as a bloc <strong>and</strong> the rest of the EAC states<br />

69


perform worse than food sector too. At the EAC, the coefficient is-0.6, correspond<strong>in</strong>g to a<br />

performance of 45 percent less than the average contribution of the food sector on exports. And<br />

for Burundi, Kenya, Tanzania <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a, the coefficients are -1.54, -0.59, -0.77 <strong>and</strong> -4.23<br />

respectively. These correspond to average performances of 79 percent, 45 percent, 54 percent<br />

<strong>and</strong> 99 percent less than the food sector. A similar trend is observed for ores <strong>and</strong> metals. And the<br />

correspond<strong>in</strong>g coefficient estimates of the Bloc, Burundi, Kenya, Tanzania <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a are -<br />

1.78, -2.16, -2.50, -1.05 <strong>and</strong> -2.62 respectively. In terms of percentage they are equal to 83<br />

percent, 88 percent, 92 percent, 65 percent <strong>and</strong> 93 percentrespectively.<br />

70


Chapter Six<br />

6.0 Summary, Conclusion <strong>and</strong> Policy Recommendations<br />

6.1 Introduction<br />

The conclusions of the study are presented <strong>in</strong> this chapter. Section 6.2 summarizes the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

of the study.Conclusions are then generated from these f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> section 6.3. Policy<br />

recommendations derived from these conclusions are described <strong>in</strong> section 6.4.<br />

6.2 Summary of the Empirical Analysis<br />

The study sought to answer three broad questions about the impact of the EAC adopted trade<br />

liberalization policy (or preferential trade liberalization or EAC trade agreement) on its partner<br />

states viz: the first question related to determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g which covariates expla<strong>in</strong> trade; the second,<br />

sought to estimate the effect on the sectoral trad<strong>in</strong>g patterns; <strong>and</strong> the third, was to assess the trade<br />

<strong>and</strong> welfare effects. An extended gravity model was run with a panel dataset extend<strong>in</strong>g 22 years<br />

(from 1988 to 2009). The dataset <strong>in</strong>cluded 168 countries <strong>and</strong> five major products or sectors of<br />

EAC <strong>in</strong>terest. The Poisson fixed effects estimation technique was used to run the gravity model<br />

for EAC, Burundi, Kenya, Rw<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Kenya. Due to lack of convergenceof Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s trade<br />

data, its estimates were determ<strong>in</strong>ed by the least squares dummy variable estimation. All the<br />

regressions were run us<strong>in</strong>g a two-way fixed-effects model.<br />

For objective one, the study found out that the gravity model expla<strong>in</strong>ed the trade pattern.<br />

And of thecanonical gravity model covariates, the coefficients of distance, the importer GDP <strong>and</strong><br />

GDP per capita , shar<strong>in</strong>g a common border, shar<strong>in</strong>g official <strong>and</strong> ethnographic language, ever<br />

be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a colonial relationship <strong>and</strong> the trad<strong>in</strong>g country-pair ever be<strong>in</strong>g the same country, had<br />

positive <strong>and</strong> significant <strong>in</strong>fluences on trade at the regional level. At the country level, the GDP of<br />

71


the importer positively <strong>in</strong>fluenced the exports of all the countries. Another covariate which<br />

affected (reduced trade) trade<strong>in</strong> all the countries except Burundi,probably because of its th<strong>in</strong><br />

exports base, was the distance covariate. Trad<strong>in</strong>g with a country that rema<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the same<br />

colonial relationship with EAC after 1945<strong>in</strong>fluenced trade more positively than with a partner<br />

who did not. Burundi <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s exports responded more to trad<strong>in</strong>g with a partner who has<br />

ever been <strong>in</strong> the same colonial relation than if Burundi <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a traded with a country that<br />

had never been <strong>in</strong> the same colonial relation with them. Trad<strong>in</strong>g with a contiguous country<br />

benefited Kenya‟s <strong>and</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a‟s exports more than trad<strong>in</strong>g with a country that was not<br />

contiguous to them. Another positive <strong>in</strong>fluence was observed when the trad<strong>in</strong>g was with a<br />

country that was <strong>in</strong> a colonial relationship with it than with one which had never been <strong>in</strong> such an<br />

arrangement. Kenya‟s exports are also <strong>in</strong>fluenced positively by size of its partners GDP per<br />

capita <strong>and</strong> its own GDP size. Furthermore, when Kenya trades with a country that was once the<br />

same country with it, <strong>and</strong> a country that use the same official language as it, it benefits more than<br />

trad<strong>in</strong>g with one that is otherwise.<br />

For the second objective relat<strong>in</strong>g to the effect of EAC trade agreement on sectoral trade<br />

patterns with reference to the food sector, the study found out that:<br />

Inthe EAC bloc, the food sector performed better than all the other sectors – agricultural raw<br />

materials, fuels, ores <strong>and</strong> metals, <strong>and</strong> the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sectors. For example, <strong>in</strong> relation to<br />

the food sector, the agricultural raw materials sector, fuels, ores <strong>and</strong> metals <strong>and</strong> manufactures<br />

performance are 28 percent, 45 percent, 83 percent <strong>and</strong> 67 percent respectively.<br />

In Burundi, a similar pattern is observed <strong>in</strong> the food sector performs better than all the other<br />

sectors. The agricultural raw materials, fuel, ores <strong>and</strong> metals, <strong>and</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sectors‟<br />

performance is 80 percent, 79 percent, 88 percent, <strong>and</strong> 79 percent respectively worse than the<br />

food sector.<br />

Food exports of Kenya performed better than all the other sectors of its exports. For<br />

example, the agricultural raw materials sector performed worse than the food sector by 21<br />

percent. The fuels, ores <strong>and</strong> metals, <strong>and</strong> manufactures performed worse than the food sector<br />

by 45 percent, 92 percent <strong>and</strong> 12 percent on average.<br />

In Rw<strong>and</strong>a, it is only the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector that performed worse than the food sector by<br />

85 percent on average. However, the agricultural raw materials, fuels <strong>and</strong> ores <strong>and</strong> metals<br />

perform better than the agricultural sector by 27 percent, 1260 percent <strong>and</strong> 57 percent on<br />

average.<br />

In Tanzania, the food sector performed better than the other sectors that contributed to its<br />

exports. For example, the agricultural raw materials performed 21 percent worse than the<br />

food sector.The fuels, ores <strong>and</strong> metals, <strong>and</strong> manufactures sectors performancewas worse than<br />

the food sector on average by 54 percent, 65 percent <strong>and</strong> 85 percent respectively.<br />

72


In Ug<strong>and</strong>a, as similar to the performance observed <strong>in</strong> Burundi, Kenya <strong>and</strong> Tanzania <strong>in</strong> the<br />

performance of the food sector <strong>in</strong> relation to the other sectors. The agricultural raw materials,<br />

fuels, ores <strong>and</strong> metals, <strong>and</strong> manufacturessectors performed worse than the food sector by 80<br />

percent, 99 percent, 93 percent <strong>and</strong> 17 percent respectively.<br />

In the descriptive section, it was observed that the EAC bloc exports grew from less than<br />

US$ 2 billion <strong>in</strong> 1988 to currently US$ 10 billion. The major contribut<strong>in</strong>g sector to exports<br />

was the food whose contribution on average was more thanUS$ 3 billion over the period<br />

under review. The manufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> agricultural raw materials sector is the second major<br />

contributor to these exports, jo<strong>in</strong>tly contribut<strong>in</strong>g about US$ 4 billion currently.Ores <strong>and</strong><br />

metals, <strong>and</strong> the fuels sectors account for the rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g portion of the bloc exports. Kenya is<br />

the dom<strong>in</strong>ant producer of the exports of EAC, produc<strong>in</strong>g an average of US$ 3 billionover the<br />

period. Tanzania <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a contribute on average less than US$ 2 billion <strong>and</strong> US$ 1 billion<br />

of the bloc‟s exports. Rw<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Burundi on average contribute less than US$ 0.5 billion<br />

over the period.<br />

Intra bloc exports have grown from less than US$ 100 million to US$ 2000 million over the<br />

1988 to 2009 period. Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector as the major contributor to <strong>in</strong>tra bloc exports,<br />

accounts for US$ 600 million on average. Fuel sector is the second major <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc<br />

contributor, with an average of less than US$ 250 million over the period. Food sector<br />

follows <strong>in</strong> third position contribut<strong>in</strong>g aboutUS$ 180 million over the period. Agricultural raw<br />

materials<strong>and</strong> ores <strong>and</strong> metals sectors had a peripheral contribution to the <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports.<br />

Kenya is the largest contributor of the <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports. This is followed by Tanzania <strong>and</strong><br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a which contribute a jo<strong>in</strong>t value of about 20 percent of Kenya‟s <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports.<br />

Burundi <strong>and</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a contribute an <strong>in</strong>significant value of the <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports.<br />

From the graphics <strong>in</strong> the descriptive section, it is clear that both the <strong>in</strong>ter-bloc <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>tra bloc<br />

exports <strong>in</strong>creased tremendously when the EAC was formed <strong>in</strong> 2000 to 2009. There is also a<br />

further movement <strong>in</strong> the trends with Burundi <strong>and</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a jo<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the EAC. However, the<br />

trends seem to slightly dampen from 2008 probably due to the effect of the global f<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

crisis.<br />

In review<strong>in</strong>g the EAC protocol, the food sector was a component of the chapter on<br />

agriculture <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terventions to improve both were synergized to almost all other<br />

<strong>in</strong>terventions of EAC. There were also no clear policies to enhance the output or even trade<br />

<strong>in</strong> agricultural sector <strong>and</strong> food trade.<br />

And for objective three, relat<strong>in</strong>g to assess<strong>in</strong>g the effects of EAC trade agreement on the trade <strong>and</strong><br />

welfare effects, the study foundout that;<br />

The EAC agreement led to creation of trade at the bloc level of about 5 percent than<br />

otherwise.<br />

73


The EAC trade agreement led to a reduction <strong>in</strong> the welfare of non-members (rest of the<br />

world).<br />

Kenya‟s membership to the bloc has enabled it to create more trade than if it was not a<br />

member. The trade created has exp<strong>and</strong>ed by 361 percent on average.<br />

Tanzania‟s membership of the EAC bloc dampened it trade creation by 55 percent than if it<br />

was not a member.<br />

6.3 Conclusions<br />

The results of this study suggest that:<br />

The EAC trade liberalization policy reform that led to the formation of the EAC trade<br />

agreement has tremendously led to the growth <strong>and</strong> expansion of exports <strong>in</strong> all the sectors of<br />

food, agricultural raw materials, fuels, ores <strong>and</strong> metals, <strong>and</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sectors. However,<br />

this growth is more reflective <strong>in</strong> the food sector on the one h<strong>and</strong>, followed by the agricultural<br />

raw materials <strong>and</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector on the other h<strong>and</strong>, more than the growth <strong>in</strong> the fuels<br />

<strong>and</strong> ores <strong>and</strong> metals sectors at the bloc level.<br />

Kenya is the biggest beneficiary from this growth, followed by Tanzania <strong>and</strong> Ug<strong>and</strong>a, while<br />

Burundi <strong>and</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a were relegated beneficiaries but had a limp-frogg<strong>in</strong>g export growth.<br />

Intra-bloc exports <strong>in</strong>creased tremendously across all the sectors. However, the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g<br />

sector exports dom<strong>in</strong>ate the <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc exports. The fuels sectors exports, though very small<br />

compared to the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector exports follows <strong>in</strong> tow. This is closely followed by the<br />

food sector exports. The fuels <strong>and</strong> ores <strong>and</strong> metals sectors are also relegated to the much<br />

lower growth <strong>in</strong> the bloc too. It would be expected that s<strong>in</strong>ce the food sector constituted the<br />

largest export growth without the bloc, it would also follow that it is the major <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc<br />

export. However, this is not the case, s<strong>in</strong>ce the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector dom<strong>in</strong>ates <strong>in</strong>tra-bloc<br />

exports. The reasons for the disparity of such an export outlay were beyond the coverage of<br />

this study.<br />

The choice of the importer mattered a lot <strong>in</strong> expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g EAC bloc exports. Importers of EAC<br />

export products that have large GDPs <strong>in</strong>fluenced trade more than those with trifl<strong>in</strong>g GDPs,<br />

ceteris paribus.<br />

Distance is an important factor <strong>in</strong> expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the volume of exports from the EAC bloc.<br />

Proximate importers <strong>in</strong>fluenced trade more than detached import<strong>in</strong>g countries.<br />

The implementation of the EAC trade agreement led to a creation of trade of more than 5<br />

percent on average than that expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the reference.<br />

The adopted EAC policy reform has led to an export diversion of about 19 percent on<br />

average than predicted by the reference.<br />

74


By <strong>in</strong>ference, the implementation of the EAC trade agreement led to a reduction <strong>in</strong> the<br />

welfare of non-members (or the rest of the world).<br />

Kenya‟s membership <strong>in</strong> the EAC <strong>and</strong> its implementation of the trade agreement led to Kenya<br />

creat<strong>in</strong>g more trade than was predicted by reference. The trade created by Kenya was about<br />

361 percent on average.<br />

Tanzania‟s membership <strong>and</strong> adoption of the EAC trade agreement reduced their trade<br />

creation by 55 percent on average than was predicted by reference or if it did not implement<br />

the trade liberalization m<strong>and</strong>ate.<br />

The EAC policies on food trade <strong>in</strong> particular, <strong>and</strong> agriculture <strong>in</strong> general, is a mumbo-jumbo<br />

of policies. The <strong>in</strong>terventions to enhance these sectors is synergized to every other sector,<br />

<strong>in</strong>terventions or programs from rural development, <strong>in</strong>vestment, climate change, <strong>in</strong>frastructure<br />

development, to poverty reduction, among others. As such, it becomes difficult for the food<br />

<strong>and</strong> agricultural sectors (sectors important for food security <strong>and</strong> trade) to receive tangible <strong>and</strong><br />

targeted support. Even with<strong>in</strong> the Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Food Security chapter of the EAC trade<br />

Protocol, the food sector is fused <strong>in</strong> agricultural <strong>and</strong> rural development programs, without<br />

clear guidel<strong>in</strong>es to improve the sector at the EAC bloc level, at least.<br />

6.4 Policy Recommendations<br />

The policy recommendations derived from these conclusions are:<br />

• There is need to look at the structural components that h<strong>in</strong>der Tanzania to create trade as a<br />

member of EAC. These h<strong>in</strong>drances possibly emanate from <strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>in</strong>adequacies <strong>and</strong><br />

NTBs to l<strong>in</strong>k Tanzania to its trad<strong>in</strong>g partners. The EAC Summit should strategize mutually to<br />

solve this by possibly <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g a trust fund to support especially the <strong>in</strong>frastructural<br />

limitations. There seems to be already <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>itiative to construct the Tanga-Mwanza Railway<br />

to l<strong>in</strong>k Dar es Salaam port to the h<strong>in</strong>terl<strong>and</strong> to provide an alternative route <strong>and</strong> reduce on<br />

transportation expenditures, however, this has taken too long too. It is also recommended that<br />

such an <strong>in</strong>itiative should be extended to l<strong>in</strong>k Burundi <strong>and</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a too.<br />

• M<strong>in</strong>us Kenya, there is need for the other EAC members to build their export base <strong>and</strong><br />

diversify the range of products they export (this is particularly recommended for Burundi <strong>and</strong><br />

Rw<strong>and</strong>a). Where diversification is not tenable, the regional body should identify sectors that<br />

each country could specialize as it export sector, to avoid duplication of export sectors <strong>and</strong><br />

enhance the exploitation of the available resources maximally.<br />

• As the EAC is exp<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> size, it‟s important that the choice of its partners considered with<br />

economic rationale more than us<strong>in</strong>g the legal or political criterion. The EAC should <strong>in</strong> the<br />

medium term consider only accession partners with high GDP per capita, otherwise, those<br />

with low GDP per capita dampen the economic prospects of the bloc.<br />

75


• In similar light, as EAC is busy look<strong>in</strong>g for importers of its products, it is important that it<br />

sticks to importers who have high GDPs s<strong>in</strong>ce they enhance trade more than those that do not<br />

ceteris paribus. It is also imperative that the partners to consider the proximity of the<br />

importer, the language they use both official <strong>and</strong> ethnographic, <strong>and</strong> their historical experience<br />

relat<strong>in</strong>g to colonization s<strong>in</strong>ce these enhance trade more than consider<strong>in</strong>g importers who are<br />

otherwise.<br />

• There is also need for EAC to develop a range of strategic policies to streaml<strong>in</strong>e the food <strong>and</strong><br />

agricultural sector <strong>and</strong> their sub-sectors. The cloud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> fusion of the food with other<br />

sectors should be separate, <strong>and</strong> let the food sector <strong>and</strong> possibly, other sector <strong>in</strong>terventions not<br />

be synergized <strong>in</strong> a manner that will h<strong>in</strong>der their faster growth. This affects resource<br />

allocation, s<strong>in</strong>ce the EAC may not know where to allocate it scare resources. It is<br />

recommended that the EAC could align peg it sectors after the WTO, such as the agreement<br />

on agriculture.<br />

76


References<br />

Anderson J.E. (1979) “A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation”, AER, 69(1):106-116<br />

Anderson J. <strong>and</strong> E. Van W<strong>in</strong>coop (2003) “Gravity with Gravitas: A solution to the Border<br />

Puzzle” AER, 93:170-192.<br />

Appleyard, D <strong>and</strong> Field, A. J. (2001). “International Economics – <strong>Trade</strong> Theory <strong>and</strong> Policy”, 4th<br />

edition, Irw<strong>in</strong> –Chicago.<br />

Benjam<strong>in</strong>, R. (2004). A gravity Study of the Proposed Ch<strong>in</strong>a-ASEAN Free <strong>Trade</strong> Area. The<br />

International <strong>Trade</strong> Journal, 18(2), 335 – 353.<br />

Bergstarnd J.H. (1990) “The Heckscher-Ohl<strong>in</strong>-Samuelson model, the L<strong>in</strong>der Hypothesis, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Determ<strong>in</strong>ants of Bilateral Intra-<strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>Trade</strong>” Economic Journal, 100(4):1216-1229<br />

Bhagwati, J. (1991). The World trad<strong>in</strong>g System <strong>and</strong> Risk. Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton University Press.<br />

Carrere, C. (2004). Revisit<strong>in</strong>g the effects of <strong>Regional</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> Agreements on <strong>Trade</strong> Flows with<br />

Proper Specification of the Gravity Model. European Economic Review 50(2006) 223-<br />

247.<br />

Cernat, L. (2001). Assess<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Regional</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> Arrangements: Are South-South RTAs More <strong>Trade</strong><br />

Divert<strong>in</strong>g? Policy Issues <strong>in</strong> International <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>and</strong> Commodities. Study Series No. 6.<br />

United Nations Conference on <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>and</strong> Development. New York <strong>and</strong> Geneva.<br />

Deardoff (1998)”Determ<strong>in</strong>ants of Bilateral <strong>Trade</strong>: Does Gravity Work <strong>in</strong> a Neoclassical<br />

Framework?” <strong>in</strong> J.A. Frankel (ed.). The <strong>Regional</strong>ization of the World Economy, Chicago:<br />

University of Chicago Press<br />

Dell‟Aquila, C. Sarker, R. <strong>and</strong> Meike, K. D. (1999). <strong>Regional</strong>ism <strong>and</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Agrifood</strong><br />

<strong>Products</strong>. Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 99-5, International Agriculture trade Research Consortium, St.<br />

Paul, MN.<br />

Diao, X. Rose, T. <strong>and</strong> Somwaru. (1999). What is the Cause of Growth <strong>in</strong> <strong>Regional</strong> <strong>Trade</strong>: <strong>Trade</strong><br />

Liberalization or RTA? The Case of Agriculture. Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 56, International<br />

Agriculture <strong>Trade</strong> Research Consortium, St Paul, MN.<br />

Dissanayake, S. <strong>and</strong> Weerahawa, J. (2009). <strong>Trade</strong> Creation <strong>and</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> Diversion Effects of<br />

Agricultural <strong>Trade</strong>. Proceed<strong>in</strong>gs from the Asia-Pacific <strong>Trade</strong> Economists‟ Conference on<br />

<strong>Trade</strong>-Led Growth <strong>in</strong> Times of Crisis. Organized by the United Nations ESCAP <strong>and</strong><br />

ATNeT.<br />

77


Egger, P. (2002). Estimat<strong>in</strong>g regional trad<strong>in</strong>g bloc effects with panel data. Review of World<br />

Economics, Vol. 140, No 1, pp 151-166<br />

Either, Wilfred.(1983). Modern International Economics. W. W. Norton Company, Inc.<br />

Frankel, A. J. (1997). <strong>Regional</strong> Trad<strong>in</strong>g Blocs <strong>in</strong> World Economic Systems.Peterson Institute for<br />

International Economics, number 72<br />

Grant, J. <strong>and</strong> Lamber, D. M. (2005). <strong>Regional</strong>ism <strong>in</strong> World Agriculture <strong>Trade</strong>. Lessons from<br />

Gravity Model estimate. A Paper Selected for Presentation at the American Agricultural<br />

Economics Association‟s Annual Meet<strong>in</strong>g, Providence. Rhode isl<strong>and</strong>. July 24 -27, 2005.<br />

Gregory, R. G. (1981). Co-operation <strong>and</strong> Collaboration <strong>in</strong> Colonial East Africa: The Asians‟<br />

Political Role. African Affairs, 80, 259-273.<br />

Gujarati, N. D. (2004). Basic Econometrics. 4 th Edition. West Po<strong>in</strong>t Military Academy.<br />

Head, Keith (2003). Gravity for Beg<strong>in</strong>ners. Mimeo, University British Columbia. Cited from<br />

www.economics.ca/Keith/gravity.pdf.<br />

Head, K. <strong>and</strong> Ries, J. (2004). <strong>Regional</strong>ism with multilateralism: The WTO <strong>Trade</strong> Policy review<br />

of Canada. The World Economy.<br />

Helpman, E. Melitz, M. <strong>and</strong> Rub<strong>in</strong>sta<strong>in</strong>, Y. (2008). Trad<strong>in</strong>g Partners <strong>and</strong> Trad<strong>in</strong>g Volumes.<br />

Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 12927. National Bureau of Economics Research.<br />

http://www.nber.org/papers/w12927.<br />

Heston, A., Summers, R. <strong>and</strong> Aten, B. (2009). Penn World Table Version 6.3, Center for<br />

International Comparisons of Production, Income <strong>and</strong> Prices at the University of<br />

Pennsylvania.<br />

Holden, M. (2003). Stages of Economic <strong>Integration</strong>: From Autarky to Economic Union. Cited<br />

from Publication.gc.ca.<br />

Jayas<strong>in</strong>ghe, S. <strong>and</strong> Sarker, Rakhal, R. (2004). Effects of regional <strong>Trade</strong> Agreements on trade <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>Agrifood</strong> <strong>Products</strong>: Evidence from Gravity model<strong>in</strong>g Us<strong>in</strong>g Disaggregated Data. Center<br />

for Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural Development, Lowa State University.<br />

Kessie, E. (2004). The Doha Development Agenda after the Hong Kong M<strong>in</strong>isterial Conference:<br />

Narrow<strong>in</strong>g the Gaps <strong>in</strong> Members' Negotiat<strong>in</strong>g Positions.<br />

Kirkpatrick, C. <strong>and</strong> Watanabe, M. (2005). <strong>Regional</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan Africa: An Analysis of<br />

East African <strong>Trade</strong> Cooperation, 1970-2001. Manchester School, Vol 73 No. 3 pp 141-<br />

164.<br />

78


Krugman, P. <strong>and</strong> Obstfeld, M. (2009), International Economics: Theory <strong>and</strong> Policy, 8th ed.<br />

Boston, MA: Addison Wesley. ISBN: 0321278844.<br />

Mayers, T. <strong>and</strong> Zignago, S. (2006). Notes on CEPII‟s Distances Measures. Accessed from<br />

www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/bdd/distances.htm<br />

Mahoney, M., Trigg, R., Griff<strong>in</strong>, M., <strong>and</strong> Pustay, M. (1998). Techniques for Analyz<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Industries <strong>and</strong> Competitors: New York: Free Press.<br />

Obsfeld, M. <strong>and</strong> Rogoff, M. (2001). The Six major puzzles <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational macroeconomics. Is<br />

there a common cause? NBER Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 7777.<br />

Ochwada, H. (2004). Reth<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g East African <strong>Integration</strong>: From Economic to Political <strong>and</strong> From<br />

State to Civil society. Council for the Development of Social Science Research <strong>in</strong> Africa<br />

(CODESERIA). Vol. XXIX, No. 2.<br />

OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation <strong>and</strong> development). (1997). The Uruguay Round<br />

Agreement on Agriculture. OECD, Paris.<br />

Polak, J. (2007). Is APEC a Natural <strong>Regional</strong> Trad<strong>in</strong>g bloc? A critique of the Gravity Model of<br />

International <strong>Trade</strong>. The World Economy, 19(5), 533-543.<br />

Rojid, S. (2006). COMESA <strong>Trade</strong> Potential: A gravity Approach. Applied Economic Letters,<br />

13(14), 947 – 951.<br />

Salvatore, D. (2004). International Economics. 8 th Edition. John Wiley & sons, Inc.<br />

Sarker, R. <strong>and</strong> Jayas<strong>in</strong>ghe, S. (2007). <strong>Regional</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> Agreements <strong>and</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Agrifood</strong><br />

<strong>Products</strong>: Evidence for the European Union from Gravity Model<strong>in</strong>g Us<strong>in</strong>g Disaggregated<br />

Data. Agricultural Economics. Vol. 34(1): 93 – 104.<br />

Schiff, M., <strong>and</strong> W<strong>in</strong>ters A. L. (1998). Dynamics <strong>and</strong> Politics <strong>in</strong> <strong>Regional</strong> <strong>Integration</strong><br />

Arrangements: An Introduction, <strong>in</strong>: The World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 12, No. 2.<br />

Serrano, R. <strong>and</strong> P<strong>in</strong>illa, V. (2010). Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Food <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>in</strong> European Union Countries<br />

(1963 – 2000). A Gravity Equation Approach. DT-AEHE No. 1007. Cited from<br />

www.aehe.net.<br />

Shams, R. (2003). <strong>Regional</strong> <strong>Integration</strong> <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries: Some Lessons Based on Case<br />

Studies. HWWA Discussion Paper 251.Hamburgisches Welt-Wirtschafts-Archiv<br />

(HWWA) Hamburg Institute of International Economics.<br />

Silva, J. S. <strong>and</strong> Tenreyro, S. (2006). The Log of Gravity. Discussion Paper Series No. 5311.<br />

International Macroeconomics <strong>and</strong> International trade. Center for Economics Policy<br />

Research. www.cepr/pubs/dps/DP5311.asp<br />

79


Soloaga, I. <strong>and</strong> W<strong>in</strong>ters, L. A. (2001). “<strong>Regional</strong>ism <strong>in</strong> the N<strong>in</strong>eties: What Effect on <strong>Trade</strong>?”<br />

North American Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>and</strong> Economics 12(1):1-29.<br />

Stock, H. J <strong>and</strong> Watson, W. M. (2003). Introduction to Econometrics. Addision-Wesley Higher<br />

Education Group.<br />

Subramanian, A. <strong>and</strong> Wei, S, J. (2003). The WTO Promotes <strong>Trade</strong>, Strongly But Unevenly.<br />

National Bureau of Economics Research (NBER). Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 10024.<br />

Suranovic,S.M., International <strong>Trade</strong> Theory <strong>and</strong> Policy (onl<strong>in</strong>e at<br />

http://<strong>in</strong>ternationalecon.com/<strong>Trade</strong>/T-toc.php).<br />

T<strong>in</strong>bergen, J. (1962). Shap<strong>in</strong>g the World Economy: Suggestions for an International Economic<br />

Policy. New York: The Twentieth Century Fund.<br />

Trivedi, P. K. (2009). Microeconomics Us<strong>in</strong>g Stata. A Stata Press Publication. Stata Press, 4905<br />

Lakeway Drive, College Station, Texas.<br />

Virtual Institute – United Nations Conference on <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>and</strong> Development. (2007). Teach<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Material on <strong>Regional</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> Agreements. Access from http://vi.unctad.org/resourcesma<strong>in</strong>menu-64/teach<strong>in</strong>g-materials-ma<strong>in</strong>menu-65/33-vi-teach<strong>in</strong>g-material-on-regionaltrade-agreements.<br />

Vylder, S. D. (2007). The Least Countries <strong>and</strong> World <strong>Trade</strong> – Second Edition. Sida Studies No.<br />

19.<br />

Westerlund, J. <strong>and</strong> Wilhelmsson, F. (2006). Estimat<strong>in</strong>g the gravity Model without Gravity Us<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Panel Data. Accessed from at www.nek.lu.se.<br />

Wanjiru, Ng‟ ang‟a, 2006. The “New” East African Community: Effects on <strong>Trade</strong>, Welfare, <strong>and</strong><br />

Productive Activities <strong>in</strong> East Africa. Unpublished M.A. Dissertation Submitted to the<br />

University of Sasktchewan, Saskotoon, SK.<br />

World Bank. (2000). <strong>Trade</strong> Blocks, Oxford University Press, New York<br />

Wooldgridge, J. M. (2004). Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach. South-Western<br />

College Pub; 2 Edition.<br />

80


Appendix A: List of Tables<br />

List of Appendices<br />

Table 4.2 Composition of Food Item us<strong>in</strong>g the SITC Revision 3 (1 to 3 digits)<br />

Panel A<br />

Cod<br />

es Food Item Product Group (0+1+22+4)<br />

0 Food & Live animals<br />

1 Beverages <strong>and</strong> tobacco<br />

22 Oil seeds/oil fruits<br />

4 Animal/veg oil/fat/wax<br />

Panel B<br />

Cod Agricultural raw materials (AgriRaw) (2 -<br />

es (22 +27 +28))<br />

2 Crude mater.ec food/fuel<br />

02 UN Special Code<br />

21 Hide/sk<strong>in</strong>/fur, raw<br />

23 Crude/synthet/rec rubber<br />

24 Cork <strong>and</strong> wood<br />

25 Pulp <strong>and</strong> waste paper<br />

26 Textile fibres<br />

29 Crude anim/veg mater nes<br />

Panel C<br />

Cod<br />

es Ores <strong>and</strong> metals (OresMtls) (27+ 28+ 68)<br />

27 Crude fertilizer/m<strong>in</strong>eral<br />

28 Metal ores/metal scrap<br />

68 Non-ferrous metals<br />

Panel D<br />

Codes Fuels (3)<br />

Panel E<br />

Cod<br />

es<br />

3 M<strong>in</strong>eral fuels/lubricants<br />

32 Coal/coke/briquettes<br />

33 Petroleum <strong>and</strong> products<br />

34 Gas natural/manufactured<br />

35 Electric Current<br />

Manufactured Goods (manuf) ((5+ 6+ 7+<br />

8) - 68)<br />

5 Chemicals<strong>Products</strong>nes<br />

6 Manufactured goods<br />

60 UN Special Code<br />

61 Leather manufactures<br />

62 Rubber manufactures nes<br />

63 Cork/wood manufactures<br />

64 Paper/paperboard/article<br />

65 Textile yarn/fabric/art.<br />

66 Non-metal m<strong>in</strong>eral manuf.<br />

67 Iron <strong>and</strong> steel<br />

69 Metal manufactures nes<br />

7 Mach<strong>in</strong>ery/traspequipmt<br />

8 Miscellaneous manuf arts<br />

81


Panel A<br />

Codes Food Item Product Group (0+1+22+4)<br />

0 Food & Live animals<br />

1 Beverages <strong>and</strong> tobacco<br />

22 Oil seeds/oil fruits<br />

Panel B<br />

4 Animal/veg oil/fat/wax<br />

Codes Agricultural raw materials (AgriRaw) (2 - (22 +27 +28))<br />

2 Crude mater.ec food/fuel<br />

02 UN Special Code<br />

21 Hide/sk<strong>in</strong>/fur, raw<br />

23 Crude/synthet/rec rubber<br />

24 Cork <strong>and</strong> wood<br />

25 Pulp <strong>and</strong> waste paper<br />

26 Textile fibres<br />

29 Crude anim/veg mater nes<br />

Panel C<br />

Codes Ores <strong>and</strong> metals (OresMtls) (27+ 28+ 68)<br />

27 Crude fertilzer/m<strong>in</strong>eral<br />

28 Metal ores/metal scrap<br />

68 Non-ferrous metals<br />

Table 4.3 List of EAC Member States<br />

No. Country Name Year of Jo<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g EAC<br />

1 Burundi 2007<br />

2 Kenya 2000<br />

3 Rw<strong>and</strong>a 2007<br />

4 Tanzania 2000<br />

5 Ug<strong>and</strong>a 2000<br />

82


Table 4.4 List of Importers of EAC Sector <strong>Products</strong><br />

Panel A Panel B Panel C<br />

No. Country No. Country No. Country<br />

1 Afghanistan 57 France 113 Niger<br />

2 Albania 58 Gabon 114 Nigeria<br />

3 Algeria 59 Gambia, The 115 Norway<br />

4 Antigua <strong>and</strong> Barbuda 60 Georgia 116 Oman<br />

5 Argent<strong>in</strong>a 61 Germany 117 Pakistan<br />

6 Armenia 62 Ghana 118 Panama<br />

7 Australia 63 Greece 119 Papua New Gu<strong>in</strong>ea<br />

8 Austria 64 Grenada 120 Paraguay<br />

9 Azerbaijan 65 Guatemala 121 Peru<br />

10 Bahamas, The 66 Gu<strong>in</strong>ea 122 Philipp<strong>in</strong>es<br />

11 Bahra<strong>in</strong> 67 Guyana 123 Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

12 Bangladesh 68 Honduras 124 Portugal<br />

13 Barbados 69 Hong Kong, Ch<strong>in</strong>a 125 Qatar<br />

14 Belarus 70 Hungary 126 Romania<br />

15 Belgium 71 Icel<strong>and</strong> 127 Russian Federation<br />

16 Belize 72 India 128 Rw<strong>and</strong>a<br />

17 Ben<strong>in</strong> 73 Indonesia 129 Sao Tome <strong>and</strong> Pr<strong>in</strong>cipe<br />

18 Bermuda 74 Iran, Islamic Rep. 130 Saudi Arabia<br />

19 Bhutan 75 Iraq 131 Senegal<br />

20 Bolivia 76 Irel<strong>and</strong> 132 Seychelles<br />

21 Bosnia <strong>and</strong> Herzegov<strong>in</strong>a 77 Israel 133 Sierra Leone<br />

22 Botswana 78 Italy 134 S<strong>in</strong>gapore<br />

23 Brazil 79 Jamaica 135 Slovak Republic<br />

24 Brunei 80 Japan 136 Slovenia<br />

25 Bulgaria 81 Jordan 137 Solomon Isl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

26 Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso 82 Kazakhstan 138 South Africa<br />

27 Burundi 83 Kenya 139 Spa<strong>in</strong><br />

28 Cambodia 84 Korea, Rep. 140 Sri Lanka<br />

29 Cameroon 85 Kuwait 141 St. Kitts <strong>and</strong> Nevis<br />

30 Canada 86 Kyrgyz Republic 142 St. Lucia<br />

31 Cape Verde 87 Latvia 143 St. V<strong>in</strong>cent <strong>and</strong> the Grenad<strong>in</strong>es<br />

32 Central African Republic 88 Lebanon 144 Sudan<br />

33 Chad 89 Lesotho 145 Sur<strong>in</strong>ame<br />

34 Chile 90 Libya 146 Swazil<strong>and</strong><br />

35 Ch<strong>in</strong>a 91 Lithuania 147 Sweden<br />

36 Colombia 92 Luxembourg 148 Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

37 Comoros 93 Macao 149 Syrian Arab Republic<br />

38 Congo, Rep. 94 Macedonia, FYR 150 Taiwan, Ch<strong>in</strong>a<br />

39 Costa Rica 95 Madagascar 151 Tanzania<br />

40 Cote d'Ivoire 96 Malawi 152 Thail<strong>and</strong><br />

83


41 Croatia 97 Malaysia 153 Togo<br />

42 Cuba 98 Maldives 154 Tr<strong>in</strong>idad <strong>and</strong> Tobago<br />

43 Cyprus 99 Mali 155 Tunisia<br />

44 Czech Republic 100 Malta 156 Turkey<br />

45 Denmark 101 Mauritania 157 Ug<strong>and</strong>a<br />

46 Djibouti 102 Mauritius 158 Ukra<strong>in</strong>e<br />

47 Dom<strong>in</strong>ica 103 Mexico 159 United Arab Emirates<br />

48 Dom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic 104 Moldova 160 United K<strong>in</strong>gdom<br />

49 Ecuador 105 Mongolia 161 United States<br />

50 Egypt, Arab Rep. 106 Morocco 162 Uruguay<br />

51 El Salvador 107 Mozambique 163 Vanuatu<br />

52 Eritrea 108 Namibia 164 Venezuela<br />

53 Estonia 109 Nepal 165 Vietnam<br />

54 Ethiopia(excludes Eritrea) 110 Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 166 Yemen<br />

55 Fiji 111 New Zeal<strong>and</strong> 167 Zambia<br />

56 F<strong>in</strong>l<strong>and</strong> 112 Nicaragua 168 Zimbabwe<br />

84


Appendix B: Correlation Matrix<br />

Figure 5.1 Show<strong>in</strong>g the Correlation matrix of the Dependent Variables <strong>and</strong> its Covariates<br />

LExports<strong>in</strong>1000usd<br />

Ldist<br />

Limportertcgdp<br />

Limportercgdp<br />

Lexportercgdp<br />

Lexporterrgdpl<br />

Limporterpop<br />

Lexporterpop<br />

lexporterxrat<br />

85


Appendix C: Estimation Results from Gravity<br />

Appendix C: Table 5.5 Results of the Estimates of the Gravity Equation on Panel Data (1988 – 2009)<br />

Results (EAC) (Burundi) (Kenya) (Rw<strong>and</strong>a) (Tanzania) (Ug<strong>and</strong>a)<br />

VARIABLES Exports Exports Exports Exports Exports LNExports<br />

Ldist -1.11*** -0.21 -1.43*** 1.28*** -1.01*** -1.06***<br />

(0.087) (0.239) (0.136) (0.223) (0.090) (0.178)<br />

Limportertcgdp 0.75*** 0.47*** 0.78*** 0.33*** 0.82*** 0.92***<br />

(0.025) (0.055) (0.037) (0.048) (0.038) (0.063)<br />

Limportercgdp 0.25*** -0.38** 0.46*** -0.59*** -0.06 -0.05<br />

(0.058) (0.169) (0.089) (0.094) (0.060) (0.113)<br />

Lexportertcgdp 0.52 12.24* 4.47 -7.25 -5.82 -0.81<br />

(2.279) (7.029) (5.586) (31.096) (44.265) (9.139)<br />

Lexportercgdp -0.01 -41.10** -10.59 14.97 7.74 2.78<br />

(2.106) (20.860) (11.528) (43.395) (56.491) (13.622)<br />

contig 0.97*** 0.12 1.02*** 2.14** 0.23 0.20<br />

(0.179) (0.740) (0.264) (1.040) (0.293) (0.742)<br />

comlang_off 0.36*** 0.27 0.52** -1.37*** 0.22 0.07<br />

(0.135) (0.467) (0.216) (0.410) (0.145) (0.406)<br />

comlang_ethno -0.73*** -0.18 -0.77*** 0.40 -0.84*** -0.32<br />

(0.154) (0.511) (0.247) (0.356) (0.133) (0.366)<br />

colony 0.01 2.02*** -0.25 0.17 0.07 1.12*<br />

(0.116) (0.205) (0.175) (0.526) (0.201) (0.611)<br />

comcol 0.05 -1.32* -0.06 1.38*** 0.22 0.31<br />

(0.109) (0.735) (0.155) (0.404) (0.138) (0.400)<br />

col45 1.46*** -0.10 1.14*** 1.86*** 1.82*** 0.68<br />

(0.187) (0.329) (0.337) (0.702) (0.329) (1.462)<br />

smctry 0.83*** 0.12 1.12*** -2.29** 0.17 0.67<br />

(0.249) (0.813) (0.310) (1.055) (0.310) (0.714)<br />

eac_exports -0.21* 0.99 -1.25 -2.76 -0.45 0.53*<br />

(0.122) (1.148) (1.981) (2.006) (1.394) (0.301)<br />

86


eac_imports 0.16 -0.50 -0.56 0.57 0.28 1.40***<br />

(0.293) (0.661) (0.387) (0.628) (0.353) (0.364)<br />

eac_<strong>in</strong>tra 0.52* 1.13 1.53*** 1.47 -0.77** -1.63***<br />

(0.278) (0.892) (0.397) (0.916) (0.385) (0.499)<br />

Agricultural Raw Materials -0.33*** -1.59*** -0.24 0.24 -0.24** -1.60***<br />

(0.114) (0.199) (0.184) (0.192) (0.109) (0.375)<br />

Fuels -0.60*** -1.54* -0.59*** 2.61*** -0.77** -4.23***<br />

(0.178) (0.823) (0.177) (0.485) (0.312) (0.659)<br />

Ores <strong>and</strong> Metals -1.78*** -2.16*** -2.50*** 0.45** -1.05*** -2.62***<br />

(0.123) (0.334) (0.131) (0.203) (0.191) (0.386)<br />

Manufactures -0.40*** -1.54*** -0.13 -1.87*** -0.49*** -1.76***<br />

(0.089) (0.225) (0.125) (0.243) (0.099) (0.288)<br />

Constant 6.73 158.39** 42.45 -30.15* 22.83 0.00<br />

(7.171) (73.268) (47.471) (17.922) (77.850) (0.000)<br />

Observations 12,117 1,141 3,900 1,348 3,193 2,535<br />

Adj. R-squared . . . . . .<br />

Number of id 439<br />

Robust st<strong>and</strong>ard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses; *** p


Appendix C: Table 5.6 EAC Bloc Results of the Estimates of the Gravity Equation on Panel Data (1988 – 2009)<br />

GLS R<strong>and</strong>om Ml R<strong>and</strong>om Effects Between Effects Population Fixed Effects<br />

Effects<br />

Model Average Model<br />

VARIABLES LExports<strong>in</strong>1000usd LExports<strong>in</strong>1000usd LExports<strong>in</strong>1000usd LExports<strong>in</strong>1000usd LExports<strong>in</strong>1000usd<br />

Ldist -1.12*** -1.12*** -0.89*** -1.12*** 0.5<br />

-0.077 -0.077 -0.101 -0.077 -0.433<br />

Limportertcgdp 0.81*** 0.81*** 0.76*** 0.81*** 0.88**<br />

-0.027 -0.028 -0.028 -0.028 -0.387<br />

Limportercgdp 0.01 0.01 -0.02 0.01 0.26<br />

-0.043 -0.043 -0.045 -0.043 -0.42<br />

Lexportertcgdp 0.74** 0.74** -2.44 0.74** 0.33<br />

-0.368 -0.367 -1.956 -0.366 -0.428<br />

Lexportercgdp -0.61 -0.61 0.37 -0.61 -0.22<br />

-0.516 -0.514 -2.659 -0.513 -0.55<br />

importerxrat 0 0 0 0 0<br />

0 0 0 0 0<br />

exporterxrat 0 0 0 0 0<br />

0 0 -0.001 0 0<br />

contig 0.08 0.08 0.46 0.08 0.17<br />

-0.245 -0.247 -0.307 -0.246 -0.448<br />

comlang_off 0.45*** 0.44*** 0.45** 0.44*** -0.14<br />

-0.145 -0.146 -0.182 -0.145 -0.252<br />

comlang_ethno -0.14 -0.14 -0.11 -0.14 0.1<br />

-0.135 -0.135 -0.177 -0.135 -0.215<br />

colony 0.81** 0.80** 1.44*** 0.81** -0.87<br />

-0.396 -0.4 -0.472 -0.398 -0.831<br />

comcol 0.13 0.13 0.26 0.13 0.03<br />

-0.127 -0.128 -0.165 -0.128 -0.207<br />

col45 0.3 0.3 0.38 0.3 0.98<br />

88


-0.547 -0.551 -0.664 -0.549 -1.07<br />

smctry 0.91*** 0.91*** 0.81* 0.91*** -0.57<br />

-0.331 -0.333 -0.463 -0.332 -0.681<br />

eac_exports -0.18*** -0.18*** -0.03 -0.18*** -0.14***<br />

-0.033 -0.033 -0.169 -0.033 -0.034<br />

eac_imports -0.34** -0.34** -0.55 -0.34** -0.27*<br />

-0.14 -0.139 -0.68 -0.139 -0.144<br />

eac_<strong>in</strong>tra 0.42** 0.41** 2.69*** 0.41** 0.22<br />

-0.207 -0.206 -0.737 -0.206 -0.218<br />

Reference Category - Food Sector<br />

Agricultural Raw<br />

Materials<br />

-0.97*** -0.97*** -0.94*** -0.97***<br />

-0.132 -0.134 -0.133 -0.133<br />

Fuels -2.36*** -2.36*** -2.35*** -2.36***<br />

-0.214 -0.216 -0.206 -0.215<br />

Ores <strong>and</strong> Metals -1.96*** -1.96*** -1.87*** -1.96***<br />

-0.158 -0.16 -0.158 -0.159<br />

Manufactures -0.94*** -0.94*** -0.89*** -0.94***<br />

-0.118 -0.119 -0.12 -0.119<br />

618b.exporter_ifs 0 0 0 0 0<br />

0 0 0 0 0<br />

Reference Category Burundi<br />

Kenya 1.79*** 1.78*** 8.51*** 1.78***<br />

-0.495 -0.494 -2.798 -0.493<br />

Rw<strong>and</strong>a 0.16 0.15 2.36*** 0.15<br />

-0.239 -0.24 -0.833 -0.239<br />

Tanzania 1.06** 1.05** 7.74*** 1.05**<br />

-0.484 -0.484 -2.445 -0.483<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a 0.43 0.42 6.53*** 0.42<br />

-0.379 -0.38 -1.658 -0.379<br />

89


Constant 1.43* 1.41* 20.01*** 1.41* -13.38***<br />

-0.825 -0.828 -2.714 -0.825 -3.762<br />

Observations 12,117 12,117 12,117 12,117 12,117<br />

R-squared 0.43 0.06<br />

Number of id 2,079 2,079 2,079 2,079 2,079<br />

Adj. R-squared . . 0.42 . -0.13<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ard Errors <strong>in</strong> Parentheses: *** p


Appendix C: Table 5.7 Comparison of EAC Country Results of the Gravity Equation on Panel Data (1988 – 2009)<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a‟s GLS R<strong>and</strong>om Kenya‟s GLS R<strong>and</strong>om Effects Burundi‟s GLS Rw<strong>and</strong>a‟s GLS Tanzania‟s ML<br />

Effects<br />

R<strong>and</strong>om Effects R<strong>and</strong>om Effects R<strong>and</strong>om Effects<br />

VARIABLES LExports<strong>in</strong>1000 LExports<strong>in</strong>1000usd LExports<strong>in</strong>1000usd LExports<strong>in</strong>1000us LExports<strong>in</strong>1000us<br />

usd<br />

d<br />

d<br />

Ldist -0.92*** -1.93*** -0.34* -0.13 -1.70***<br />

(0.149) (0.155) (0.179) (0.205) (0.173)<br />

Limportertcgdp 0.79*** 0.93*** 0.49*** 0.63*** 0.94***<br />

(0.056) (0.048) (0.069) (0.074) (0.057)<br />

Limportercgdp -0.02 0.10 -0.06 -0.19 -0.00<br />

(0.090) (0.076) (0.108) (0.118) (0.087)<br />

Lexportertcgdp -1.88 5.61** 0.51 9.76 -5.43<br />

(2.752) (2.386) (2.987) (6.861) (5.199)<br />

Lexportercgdp 2.96 -9.05** 0.60 -11.71 5.92<br />

(3.953) (4.423) (6.907) (8.418) (5.625)<br />

importerxrat 0.00 0.00** -0.00 0.00 -0.00<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

exporterxrat 0.00 -0.02 -0.00 -0.00* 0.00<br />

(0.000) (0.014) (0.001) (0.003) (0.001)<br />

contig 0.21 -0.15 0.21 -0.44 -0.44<br />

(0.506) (0.406) (0.607) (0.793) (0.526)<br />

comlang_off 0.17 0.51** 0.40 -0.32 0.87***<br />

(0.292) (0.242) (0.405) (0.444) (0.299)<br />

comlang_ethno -0.27 0.10 -0.50 0.19 -0.48*<br />

(0.273) (0.234) (0.379) (0.410) (0.272)<br />

colony 1.12 0.98 1.64** 0.53 0.02<br />

(0.960) (0.787) (0.833) (0.786) (0.853)<br />

comcol 0.21 0.24 -0.35 0.59 -0.02<br />

(0.286) (0.196) (0.388) (0.434) (0.250)<br />

col45 0.53 -1.63* 0.93 2.04* 1.73<br />

(1.357) (0.968) (1.253) (1.219) (1.170)<br />

smctry 0.52 1.07 0.28 2.10** 1.22<br />

(0.609) (0.728) (0.821) (0.924) (0.798)<br />

eac_exports -0.19* -0.14 -0.02 -0.28 -0.22*<br />

(0.113) (0.119) (0.200) (0.238) (0.132)<br />

eac_imports 1.32*** 0.01 -0.92*** -1.00*** -0.83***<br />

(0.321) (0.269) (0.356) (0.359) (0.313)<br />

eac_<strong>in</strong>tra -1.52*** 0.31 2.75*** 1.63** -0.12<br />

91


(0.451) (0.377) (0.636) (0.645) (0.436)<br />

Agricultural Raw<br />

Materials<br />

-1.47*** -0.91*** -0.65** 0.03 -1.17***<br />

(0.275) (0.235) (0.329) (0.355) (0.268)<br />

Fuels -3.72*** -2.37*** -1.69** -0.12 -3.03***<br />

(0.519) (0.363) (0.682) (0.616) (0.384)<br />

Ores & Metals -2.36*** -2.61*** -1.19*** 0.26 -2.43***<br />

(0.318) (0.280) (0.433) (0.417) (0.324)<br />

Manufactures -1.66*** -0.44* -1.36*** -0.64** -0.81***<br />

(0.241) (0.226) (0.258) (0.293) (0.248)<br />

Constant 2.54 17.32** -5.29 -7.46 24.06<br />

(2.160) (7.582) (19.315) (4.915) (15.282)<br />

Observations 2,535 3,900 1,141 1,348 3,193<br />

R-squared<br />

Number of id 439 561 271 313 495<br />

Adj. R-squared . . . . .<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ard Errors <strong>in</strong> Parentheses: *** p

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!