06.08.2013 Views

Seton Hall Magazine, Winter 2000 - Seton Hall University

Seton Hall Magazine, Winter 2000 - Seton Hall University

Seton Hall Magazine, Winter 2000 - Seton Hall University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

E c o n o m i c s<br />

Ihave been asked, as an economist,<br />

to write about “money.”<br />

It is typical to think that economists<br />

focus primarily upon<br />

money — its control, uses and<br />

abuses. But anyone who has<br />

taken a course or two in the<br />

subject matter of economics<br />

knows that money plays second<br />

fiddle to the primary concern of<br />

economists — resources.<br />

That is not to say that money<br />

hasn’t had a long and fascinating<br />

history. Nations have risen and<br />

fallen in part due to their ability<br />

or inability to manage money. But<br />

what, exactly, is the nature of<br />

money? When I receive my salary<br />

as a “direct deposit” to my bank<br />

account, is that money? When I use a<br />

phone card, is that using money? When<br />

I pay my credit card company with a<br />

check, is that pale blue piece of paper<br />

the same as money? To answer these<br />

questions one needs to understand the<br />

functions of money.<br />

Money, first of all, serves as a medium<br />

of exchange (i.e., it enables us to buy<br />

and sell goods readily and quickly, thereby<br />

reducing enormously the time that<br />

used to be spent by folks in barter<br />

economies trying to find willing partners<br />

to an exchange). Hence, money in this<br />

role has often been called the lubricant<br />

of an economy, allowing numerous transactions<br />

to flow smoothly day in and day<br />

out. Just as important, though, is<br />

money’s role as a store of value. When<br />

we work and create something useful,<br />

we are said to create value. But we may<br />

not desire to possess much of what we<br />

create and would rather have other<br />

goods and services. So we receive compensation<br />

for our efforts in the form of<br />

money, which represents the value we<br />

have produced. We can hold onto that<br />

money and use it later. Of course, we<br />

could hold onto the goods we initially<br />

created, but over time they might deteri-<br />

26 SETON HALL UNIVERSITY MAGAZINE<br />

The Mystery of Money<br />

BY FRANK D. TINARI, PH.D.<br />

“Once accumulated,<br />

money has no<br />

value in and of<br />

itself. Ask anyone<br />

with a wallet filled<br />

with cash who has<br />

ever been stranded<br />

in the wilderness<br />

what good their<br />

money did them.”<br />

orate or become<br />

obsolete. So<br />

money is a good<br />

substitute and<br />

can even earn<br />

interest for us<br />

while we retain<br />

it. This is not to<br />

say that money<br />

couldn’t lose<br />

value, especially<br />

in times of inflation. But that is another<br />

story for another time.<br />

Money is also pretty nifty in allowing<br />

us to compare values. It serves as a unit<br />

of account, a standard measuring rod,<br />

and enables us to add up the value of<br />

different items we possess. That makes<br />

lots of business and family matters easier<br />

to manage. But sometimes this function<br />

of money becomes warped into a national<br />

policy of collecting and hoarding<br />

money, which was the downfall of the<br />

mercantilist policies of the 18th century.<br />

I suppose one could call this the national<br />

version of the biblical warning that love<br />

of money is the root of evil.<br />

So now we can answer our questions.<br />

Is a check money? Yes. It is acceptable<br />

in exchange for goods, and a checking<br />

account can serve as a store of value,<br />

ready to be used whenever we wish.<br />

But a phone card and a credit card<br />

are not money themselves since one<br />

must use an actual form of money<br />

to pay for their use. Most strange,<br />

however, is direct deposit money<br />

sent in the form of electronic<br />

digits over phone lines. Since I<br />

accept it as compensation for my<br />

work, and since my bank account<br />

is credited with the amount<br />

“sent,” it is real money.<br />

But once accumulated, money<br />

has no value in and of itself. Ask<br />

anyone with a wallet filled with<br />

cash who has ever been stranded<br />

in the wilderness what good their<br />

money did them. For money has<br />

value only insofar as we can acquire<br />

real things with it. That is why we say<br />

that economics is about producing real<br />

wealth with our limited (scarce)<br />

resources, and that money is a mechanism<br />

designed to facilitate attainment of<br />

that primary goal, and not the goal itself.<br />

Nevertheless, there continues to be<br />

concern over money, especially in light<br />

of the coming boom in World Wide Web<br />

transactions, and in the increasing use of<br />

digitized forms of money. Just 20 years<br />

ago, there were fashionable predictions<br />

about the coming “cashless society.”<br />

That hasn’t materialized just yet, but we<br />

are certainly moving in that direction.<br />

It is probably safe to add that, on the<br />

one hand, as long as people lose sight of<br />

money as representing the storage value<br />

of their labor efforts, they will not use it<br />

wisely, and on the other, as long as people<br />

overly emphasize money and lose<br />

sight of the underlying goods and services<br />

it represents, that such love of<br />

money will continue to be a fundamental<br />

root of evil human behavior.<br />

BECKY HEAVNER<br />

Frank D. Tinari, Ph.D., is<br />

a professor of economics in<br />

the Stillman School of Business.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!