13.08.2013 Views

On the Optimal Taxation of Capital Income

On the Optimal Taxation of Capital Income

On the Optimal Taxation of Capital Income

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

106 JONES, MANUELLI, AND ROSSI<br />

income in <strong>the</strong> limit. <strong>On</strong>e example <strong>of</strong> this, discussed below, occurs when<br />

pure rents appear in <strong>the</strong> consumer's budget constraint. Secondly, if <strong>the</strong><br />

planner faces different constraints than <strong>the</strong> household which involve <strong>the</strong><br />

capital stock, again capital is taxed in <strong>the</strong> limit. This is <strong>the</strong> focus <strong>of</strong> our<br />

second example in which <strong>the</strong>re are two types <strong>of</strong> labor and <strong>the</strong> planner must<br />

tax <strong>the</strong>m equally. Finally, to gauge <strong>the</strong> quantitative importance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se<br />

deviations, we solve for <strong>the</strong> optimal tax system in a parameterized version<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> second example.<br />

To keep <strong>the</strong> presentation as simple as possible, from now on we restrict<br />

attention to a one capital good growth model.<br />

Consider a pseudo planner's problem given by<br />

max :<br />

t=0<br />

; t [W(c t, n t, k t, *)]&m(c 0, n 0, k 0, *, b 0)<br />

c t+x t+g t<br />

k t+1<br />

F(k t, n t)<br />

(1&$) k t+x t<br />

, i(c t, n t, k t, c t+1, n t+1, k t+1) 0 i=1, 2, ..., I,<br />

(P.4)<br />

where <strong>the</strong> interpretations <strong>of</strong> all <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> variables are as in Section 2, except<br />

that in this section, we will consider an example in which n is a vector.<br />

This problem is general enough so that one special case is <strong>the</strong> one capital<br />

good version <strong>of</strong> (P.3). More precisely, consider a standard one sector<br />

growth model where preferences are given by<br />

:<br />

t=0<br />

and <strong>the</strong> resource constraints are<br />

c t+g t+x t<br />

k t+1<br />

; t u(c t,1&n t)<br />

F(k t, n t)<br />

(1&$)k t+x t.<br />

Then, following <strong>the</strong> steps described in <strong>the</strong> previous section, it is possible<br />

to show that <strong>the</strong> Ramsey problem for this economy when <strong>the</strong> planner can<br />

choose { k<br />

t and {n<br />

t , t=1, 2, ..., can be found as <strong>the</strong> solution to (P.4) where<br />

W(c, n, k; *)#u(c, 1&n)+*[u cc&u ln],<br />

m(c 0, n 0, k 0; *)#*u c(c 0,1&n 0)[F k(k 0, n 0)(1&{ k<br />

0 )+1&$ k+b 0],<br />

and <strong>the</strong> constraints, , i(t) correspond, for example, to bounds on <strong>the</strong><br />

feasible tax rates.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!