16.08.2013 Views

Job Assignments under Moral Hazard - School of Economics and ...

Job Assignments under Moral Hazard - School of Economics and ...

Job Assignments under Moral Hazard - School of Economics and ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

3.1.2 The continuous effort model<br />

Our setup links promotion decisions to the cost <strong>of</strong> providing incentives: The principal<br />

can use a promotion as a tool to reduce implementation costs or to extract more effort<br />

from the agent. In our two-effort model, however, we do not have much flexibility in<br />

varying effort levels in <strong>and</strong> across jobs. To elaborate on the effects that varying effort<br />

levels across hierarchy levels can have, we extend our model to allow for continuous effort.<br />

Expected outputs in jobs l <strong>and</strong> h are fl(e, θ) = α e <strong>and</strong> fh(e, θ) = max {α e θ − k, 0},<br />

respectively, with k ≥ 0, θ ∈ [θ, ¯ θ] ⊆ R+. The cost <strong>of</strong> effort is c(e) = e 2 /2. Further, we<br />

impose the following technical conditions:<br />

Assumption 2<br />

(i) α ∈ (0, 1) <strong>and</strong> e ∈ [0, 1].<br />

(ii) k/α < ¯ θ < 1/α.<br />

(iii) θ < √ α 2 +2 k<br />

α<br />

< ¯ θ.<br />

The first two parts guarantee proper probability distribution functions. Specifically, (i)<br />

implies that fl(e, θ) ∈ (0, 1). And the upper bound in (ii) ensures that fh(e, θ) < 1 for all<br />

θ ∈ [θ, ¯ θ]. The lower bound guarantees that there exist interior ability levels θ ∈ (θ, ¯ θ)<br />

for which positive output in job h is possible (i.e., fh(e = 1, θ) > 0). Finally, (iii) ensures<br />

that there exists an interior first-best job assignment threshold.<br />

The ‘warm up’ cost k ≥ 0 for the more complex job h allows us to vary parametrically<br />

the difference in informativeness <strong>of</strong> output across jobs. As argued in Section 2.4, a job<br />

higher up in the hierarchy (job h) <strong>of</strong>ten is more informative about effort. Assuming k > 0<br />

captures this. Analogous to the two-effort case, the continuous version <strong>of</strong> the likelihood<br />

ratio says how informative output in job j ∈ {l, h} is about effort: rj(e, θ) = ∂<br />

∂ e fj(e,θ)<br />

fj(e,θ) .<br />

In our setup, the inverse likelihood ratios across jobs have a simple relation:<br />

1<br />

rh(e, θ) =<br />

1 k<br />

−<br />

rl(e, θ) α θ .<br />

So at k = 0 both jobs are equally informative about effort. With increasing k, job h<br />

becomes more informative about effort relative to job l. This can be seen at an intuitive<br />

level by comparing what success in a given job tells the principal about the possible<br />

effort levels that could have led to this outcome. In job l this could have been any effort<br />

level e > 0. In contrast, success in job h is more informative about effort, because a<br />

success indicates that the agent put in at least an effort <strong>of</strong> k/(α θ). Similarly, in job h<br />

output becomes less informative about effort with a higher ability level: the more able<br />

an agent the more likely it is that he succeeds even with little effort.<br />

13

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!