26.08.2013 Views

5th Annual Conference Nice - European-microfinance.org

5th Annual Conference Nice - European-microfinance.org

5th Annual Conference Nice - European-microfinance.org

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

1<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong>


2<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

The <strong>European</strong> Microcredit Research Award<br />

2008 - Fundación Nantik Lum<br />

In the frame of the EMN <strong>5th</strong> <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong>, EMN and its Spanish member<br />

Fundación Nantik Lum have launched the <strong>European</strong> Microcredit Research<br />

Award 2008.<br />

This Award is endowed with €1,000.<br />

In June 2008, EMN and Nantik Lum launched a call for research papers dealing with<br />

one of the various issues related to <strong>microfinance</strong> in Europe such as social exclusion,<br />

social and financial performance, client targeting, financial literacy, etc. The Selection<br />

Committee received 13 propositions and selected the three best of them.<br />

The final winner is going to be announced during the <strong>Conference</strong>.<br />

Additionally, the researchers are going to present their research papers in front of the<br />

audience in the <strong>Conference</strong> research strand to take place on 10th of September 2008<br />

from 8h30-10h30 moderated by Fundación Nantik Lum.<br />

This document contains the three selected research papers:<br />

S. Brana, Senior Lecturer, University Montesquieu-Bordeaux IV:<br />

“Microcredit in France: does Gender matter?”<br />

Dr. Karl Dayson, executive director, Pål Vik, research assistant, Community<br />

Finance Solutions, University of Salford, United Kingdom:<br />

“Making <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> more sustainable – lessons from Britain”<br />

Michael Unterberg, research assistant, EVERS & JUNG GmbH:<br />

“Microfinance as a <strong>European</strong> policy issue – policy images and venues”


3<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong>


Abstract<br />

Microcredit in France: does Gender matter?<br />

4<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

S. Brana, Senior Lecturer, University Montesquieu-Bordeaux IV<br />

LARE-EFI, Avenue Léon Duguit<br />

33608 Pessac<br />

00(33) 5 56 84 29 75 brana@u-bordeaux4.fr<br />

The question of the link between microcredit and gender has given rise to an<br />

abundant literature in developing countries but not in industrialised economies, where<br />

studies have focused more on women and entrepreneurship or self-employment. In both<br />

cases, however, observations are similar: women are limited to so-called feminine activities<br />

that are not very capitalistic and generate little profit. A possible explanation is that women,<br />

unlike men, do not have enough of their own funds. This leads them to opt for businesses<br />

that require little investment in terms of capital, but that will not enable them to generate a<br />

reasonable income.<br />

Microfinance institutions’ (MFIs) target poor people, excluded from the banking<br />

system. By giving them starting capital, they should thus enable a greater number of women<br />

to create their own business, but also in sectors traditionally reserved for men. Our study<br />

covers a portfolio of 3,640 microcredits in France over the 2000-2006 period. It identifies<br />

<strong>microfinance</strong> institutions’ client profiles, brings to light the men/women differences and<br />

compares them to a wider sample of entrepreneurs. We show that the men/women gap found<br />

amongst company creators is maintained amongst clients of MFIs. We also demonstrate that<br />

the gender criterion is a decisive factor of the amount of the microcredit when compared to<br />

the borrower and firm profile. To a certain extent, MFI thus reproduce gender inequalities.<br />

Key words: Microcredit, Gender, Entrepreneurship.<br />

JEL codes: G21, J16.<br />

I. Introduction<br />

Although women represent 47 % of the French working population, in 2006 they<br />

accounted for only 30% of nascent entrepreneurs. Women entrepreneurs, on average, study<br />

longer than men but have less work experience and start their business with less capital<br />

(Insee, Sine survey 2006). These reasons may explain why they face greater difficulties<br />

obtaining bank loans and funding their projects.<br />

Moreover, women are more likely to be affected by unemployment and poverty. The<br />

employment rate for women in 2005 was 57.6%, as opposed to 68.8% for men, that is a<br />

difference of 11.2%. The part-time employment rate is of 30.7%, as opposed to 5.8% for men.<br />

Women represent the majority of non-working people, of long-term unemployed, of<br />

beneficiaries of the minimum social income, or of single parent families. They are therefore<br />

particularly vulnerable to the risk of poverty.<br />

For all these reasons, women should be particularly concerned by microcredit.<br />

Microcredits are very small loans (less than 40% of the income per capita) granted to people<br />

totally or partially excluded from the banking system. In developing countries the aim of<br />

microcredit is to reduce poverty, promote self-employment and improve the empowerment of<br />

socially excluded persons, women in particular. In industrialised countries, the goal is first of<br />

all to reduce poverty by encouraging self-employment. Microcredit thus answers two types of<br />

needs (Brana, Jegourel, 2007). On the one hand, it enables people excluded from the banking


5<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

system to create their own business, on the other it provides extra funding to entrepreneurs<br />

by creating a leverage effect with respect to bank credit.<br />

Microfinance institutions (MFIs) target more specifically poor people, excluded from<br />

the banking system. By offering start-up funding, they should encourage more women to<br />

create their own business, but also to create their business in sectors that are traditionally<br />

masculine due to the initial capital they require.<br />

Our study covers a portfolio of 3640 microcredits granted in France over the 2000-<br />

2005 period. More precisely, it covers all the microcredits granted over that period in<br />

Aquitaine, the 6 th region in France, by the 12 <strong>microfinance</strong> institutions active in that region.<br />

The aim of this study is to identify the profile of these <strong>microfinance</strong> institutions’ clients, to<br />

reveal the differences between men and women and to compare them to the larger sample of<br />

entrepreneurs (using the French Institute for statistics’ database – Insee). We will then check<br />

if the “gender” criterion weighs in on the decision to grant a microcredit and on the amount<br />

of the loan. Do MFIs reduce the obstacles women face with their projects or on the contrary,<br />

do they merely reproduce these inequalities?<br />

II. Review of literature<br />

The question of the link between microcredit and gender has given rise to an<br />

abundant literature in developing countries, but not in the industrialised economies 1 . In<br />

developing countries, the debate has focused on the impact of <strong>microfinance</strong> on gender<br />

equality or empowerment of women. According to Mayoux (2007), <strong>microfinance</strong> programs,<br />

by helping women to generate an income, trigger a virtuous circle of economic<br />

empowerment, increased well-being for women and their family, and on a wider scale<br />

increased political and social power for women.<br />

Several studies, however, have qualified this positive view. Firstly, social and cultural<br />

inertia incites one to mitigate the impact of <strong>microfinance</strong>. As pointed out by Guérin and<br />

Palier (2006), whatever the quality and availability of <strong>microfinance</strong>, the road to equality is<br />

long and, even if microcredit can contribute to it, it does so only marginally.<br />

Moreover, Goes and Gupta (1996), for Bangladesh, have demonstrated that in many<br />

cases, women do not really control the use of funds that they have obtained. Indeed, because<br />

women have easier access to microcredit, men use them to get funds. For Fernando (2006),<br />

microcredit increases the responsibilities weighing on women, but not their real power, and it<br />

does not always make them less vulnerable to domestic violence.<br />

Many <strong>microfinance</strong> institutions target women primarily because they have higher<br />

repayment rates than men, their families get more benefit from their extra income, and<br />

because loan groups work better with them. It seems, however, that of 213 institutions<br />

reported by the « Microbanking Bulletin », the highest percentage of female clients is to be<br />

found in the most recent institutions. Conversely, the more mature institutions – banks, nonbank<br />

financial institutions, profit-making institutions, large scale institutions – tend to focus<br />

on the less poor of the poor and on small businesses. These large, profit-making<br />

<strong>org</strong>anisations are less likely to reach women (Cheston, 2007). In fact women, because they<br />

offer less guarantees than men and have access to smaller funds, are limited to so-called<br />

“feminine” occupations, not very capitalistic, often part-time, from home and generating little<br />

profit (Guérin, Palier 2006). The possibilities of economic empowerment and of rising above<br />

their social status remain limited.<br />

In industrialised countries, literature has focused more on women and<br />

entrepreneurship or self-employment, particularly in the United States, in Canada or in Great<br />

Britain. Anderson, Carter and Shaw (2001) thus list over 400 academic articles on women<br />

entrepreneurs. These studies reveal major differences between firms created by men and<br />

1 To our knowledge, the only study is that of T. Underwood (2006).


6<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

those created by women. They show that, compared to men, women start their own business<br />

with less financial capital, less experience and less resources in terms of human and social<br />

capital. This causes many women to set up under-funded businesses, which can have a<br />

negative impact on their long term performance. Thus the men/women differences are felt<br />

both on the structure (size of the firm, business sector) and on the profits. The performance<br />

outcomes (profitability, durability) 2 of firms managed by women are generally lower. But the<br />

impact of gender on economic performance has led to a great deal of controversy. Today<br />

however, a consensus seems to arise on the fact that if a number of variables can be<br />

controlled (business sector, starting resources, age of business), men and women’s<br />

performances will be similar (Watson 2002, Johnsen and McMahon 2005).<br />

The most important research work has focused on the issue of gender and finance<br />

(Anderson, Carter, and Shaw, 2001). Women experience more difficulties than men to raise<br />

start-up and recurrent finance. Whatever the sector or area, women start their business with<br />

about half the capital that is used by men (Brush, 1992). Moreover in surveys, women<br />

generally declare that they are or have been discriminated against by banks. The general<br />

feeling is that banks are reluctant to give them credit. There are three main types of<br />

explanations put forward for this.<br />

According to certain authors, women are discriminated against in terms of credit<br />

supply not because of their sex, but because of the less favourable characteristics of their<br />

project. Coleman and Carsky (1996) argue that businesses managed by women are less<br />

attractive for banks because they are small and considered to be more risky. Banks prefer<br />

financing larger projects that are already established which favours men. Riding and Swift<br />

(1990) compared the experience of men and women entrepreneurs in their relationship with<br />

financial institutions over a given period. They show that the financial conditions are less<br />

favourable to women, but that businesses managed by women are both younger and smaller<br />

than those managed by men, and have a weaker economic growth. Banking conditions would<br />

therefore be the result of rational banking behaviour when faced with riskier projects. It<br />

seems women also experience greater difficulty in offering guarantees. As they are more<br />

likely to be working part-time or to earn less than men, women find it more difficult to<br />

accumulate personal savings (Marlow and Patton, 2005). Thus for both these reasons, lack of<br />

personal funds puts them at a disadvantage when creating their business. Their personal<br />

contribution is limited and such a small capital cannot be used as collateral to strengthen the<br />

loan relationship. Work experience before starting a business is therefore crucial to<br />

accumulate financial capital, but also human capital and to build up a network. Whereas<br />

Fabowale and alii (1995) for Canada or Coleman (2000) for the United States demonstrate<br />

that when the firms’ characteristics are taken into account (age and size) women have equal<br />

access to credit, other studies found that structural dissimilarities cannot account for all the<br />

gender differences in financing patterns (see Carter and Shaw 2006 for a survey).<br />

Other authors focused on demand size risk and debt aversion (Bird and Brush, 2002).<br />

It seems women are less encouraged to start businesses with high growth rates that require<br />

important investments (financial and human) and prefer to avoid debt, which would explain<br />

why they do not apply for bank credits so much. Women start their business to ensure their<br />

own employment rather than to develop it. For Danes and alii (2007), because they give<br />

priorities to their families and because they are in charge of educating their children, they opt<br />

for smaller <strong>org</strong>anisation structures that are easier to manage. The 2006 Global<br />

entrepreneurship monitor survey (cf. Allen and alii, 2007) shows that fewer women than<br />

men believe they have the skills to start their own business. Women also have less selfconfidence.<br />

Whatever their reason for starting a business, they consider themselves and the<br />

entrepreneurial environment less favourably than men, which is a key point when explaining<br />

the smaller number of women in this area (Langowitz and Minniti, 2007). They are more risk<br />

averse than men (Watson et Robinson, 2003), which leads them to ask for smaller loans.<br />

2 In France, the durability rate for three year old firms is 70.4% for firms created by men and 67.7% for firms created<br />

by women.


7<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Thus, faced with similar projects, it seems difficult to pinpoint real discrimination by<br />

banks, although studies are contradictory. It seems discrimination regarding credit supply is<br />

not systematic but low (6% out of the 325 cases studied by Carter and alii 2007) and not<br />

deliberate. However, as Marlow and Patton (2005) observed, studies tend to focus on the<br />

results rather than on the process. Even though access to credit is identical for similar<br />

projects and profiles, a number of studies show that relationships with lenders are more<br />

difficult for women. Firstly, women are generally less satisfied with their banking<br />

relationship than men (Buttner and Rosen, 1988). Secondly, Carter and alii (2007) show that<br />

the trust relationship, an important aspect of the bank loan relationship, is not the same for<br />

men and women. Banks will require from women that they give proof of their knowledge on<br />

starting a business and of its different implications. Men on the other hand, are asked to<br />

demonstrate their social stability, by being married for example. Fay and Williams (1993)<br />

mailed to loan officers of major banks the files of people asking for loans where the only<br />

difference was the level of education or the sex. They demonstrate that among people with<br />

high school education, women are less likely than men to obtain a loan. For people with<br />

university education, chances are the same but the education variable will play a more<br />

important role for women. They come to the conclusion that the feeling women have of being<br />

discriminated against when asking for start up capital is grounded, but that this<br />

discrimination is probably unconscious, cultural, which makes it more difficult to change.<br />

Buttner and Rosen (1998), after surveying 106 bank loan officers, show that the<br />

characteristics associated with successful entrepreneurs are attributed to men more often<br />

than to women. Sexual stereotypes can therefore have an influence on the banking<br />

relationship in general. It seems also that women are asked more guarantees than men as<br />

well as a higher interest rate (Coleman, 2000). Riding and Swift (1990) created a witness<br />

group made up of firms managed by men, with identical characteristics in terms of age, size,<br />

business sector, growth rate and <strong>org</strong>anisation as those managed by women. They show that<br />

once these variables are controlled, there remains a significant statistical difference linked to<br />

gender. Women are asked increased collateral to obtain a credit line.<br />

Whether one is studying microcredit in developing countries or micro-firms in rich<br />

countries, similar observations can be made: women are limited to activities considered to be<br />

feminine (personal services, retail trade), to poorly capitalistic activities that generate little<br />

profit. One explanation is that women start their business with lower level of start-up<br />

capitalization. This is one of the reasons why they choose a legal structure and a type of<br />

activity that require little investment in capital but that will not enable them to generate a<br />

significant income.<br />

In industrialised countries <strong>microfinance</strong>, because it provides funding and own funds<br />

to people, particularly to women that do not have any, may encourage access to bank credit<br />

and to more ambitious projects.<br />

III. Statistical results<br />

Our research covers the activity of all <strong>microfinance</strong> institutions in Aquitaine. Over the<br />

2000-2006 period, these institutions gave just under 4,000 micro-loans amounting to a total<br />

of 18.7 million euros. We created a database using the client portfolios of these institutions.<br />

The complete data concerns 3,640 microcredit files, for a total of 17 million euros (2,381 men<br />

and 1,259 women) 3 . The advantage of this study is that it covers the almost exhaustive supply<br />

(over 90% of files contain correct information) of microcredit in the 6 th region of France<br />

during seven years.<br />

3 We excluded the data on the few businesses that were created on a family basis.


Table 1. Entrepreneurs’ characteristics<br />

Entrepreneurs<br />

(total)<br />

8<br />

Entrepreneurs<br />

with microcredit<br />

Women Men Women Men t-<br />

Student<br />

Sex 28.7% 71.3% 34.6% 65.4%<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Difference between<br />

Women and Men<br />

(with microcredit)<br />

Prob.<br />

Average age (years) 38.6 38.7 36.9 37.1 -0.632 0.527<br />

Nationality<br />

French<br />

Other<br />

Level of studies<br />

University<br />

Primary and<br />

secondary school<br />

Occupational status<br />

Active<br />

Unemployed < 1<br />

year<br />

Long term<br />

unemployed<br />

Inactive<br />

Bank credit<br />

Yes<br />

No<br />

Marital status<br />

Single<br />

Couple<br />

Work experience<br />

Yes<br />

No<br />

92%<br />

8%<br />

52.8%<br />

47.2%<br />

45.5%<br />

17.1%<br />

16.1%<br />

21.3%<br />

na<br />

na<br />

na<br />

na<br />

na<br />

na<br />

88%<br />

12%<br />

45.2%<br />

54.8<br />

57%<br />

19.3%<br />

14%<br />

9.7%<br />

na<br />

na<br />

na<br />

na<br />

na<br />

na<br />

83.9%<br />

16.2%<br />

50%<br />

50%<br />

13.4%<br />

19.3%<br />

11.2%<br />

56.1%<br />

20.1%<br />

79.9%<br />

60.8%<br />

39.2%<br />

49.4%<br />

50.6%<br />

81.1%<br />

18.9%<br />

39.2%<br />

60.8%<br />

17.3%<br />

21.5%<br />

10%<br />

51.2%<br />

23.6%<br />

76.4%<br />

42.2%<br />

57.8%<br />

*** Differences between men and women are significant at the .01 level.<br />

* Differences between men and women are significant at the .1 level.<br />

Sources: Our database and the Sine database of the Insee.<br />

55%<br />

45%<br />

1.917<br />

5.091<br />

-2.769<br />

-1.408<br />

1.084<br />

3.58<br />

5.784<br />

9.984<br />

-3.016<br />

0.055*<br />

0,000***<br />

0.006***<br />

0.159<br />

0.278<br />

0.000***<br />

0.000***<br />

0.000***<br />

0.003***<br />

34.6% of microcredits reported in our survey were disbursed to women. This rate is<br />

slightly above the percentage of women company creators in France (28.7% in 2002), but it is<br />

lower than the <strong>European</strong> rates (respectively 39% and 30% in 2004). The percentage of<br />

women in the MFIs portfolio is close to the Western <strong>European</strong> rate but is in contrast with the<br />

East <strong>European</strong> (62%) and North American (59%) rates, as well as with those of developing<br />

countries (84%).<br />

As shown in Table 1, of all entrepreneurs, <strong>microfinance</strong> institutions tend to target<br />

relatively more women, young people, foreign born populations, as well as people who are<br />

excluded from the labour market. Because of their characteristics, these people are often the<br />

ones that do not have much personal funding, which makes access to a classic bank credit<br />

more difficult. Moreover the number of women who start their business alone is generally<br />

higher than for men who are often helped by their partner (or by a family member). Thus<br />

women, who are often single, will a priori have less income and less guarantees (single source<br />

of income, fewer assets) to put forward in order to get external financing. Yet they have a


9<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

monthly income that is almost equivalent to that of men (the difference is not statistically<br />

significant, see Table 2). Moreover, it is interesting to note that a high percentage of single<br />

female borrowers have children in their care (44.4% of single women, as opposed to only<br />

14.2% of single men). And yet, it is well known that the risk of poverty is 34% amongst singleparent<br />

families. In our database, almost 80% of these women benefit from the minimum<br />

social income or other benefits and 96.7% of them are excluded from bank funds. Conversely,<br />

men who have loans and are in a couple have children more often than women who are in a<br />

couple (73.8 % compared to 66.6%).Consequently, self employment for single women may be<br />

perceived as a necessity entrepreneurship, whereas it may be an opportunity<br />

entrepreneurship for women in couple.<br />

The male/female difference amongst microcredit beneficiaries does not appear to be<br />

significant when compared to the reference population of company creators. In both samples<br />

women have studied more than men but have less work experience in the sphere they are<br />

entering. Most of the time they were outside of the workforce (but not on unemployment<br />

benefits) before they created their business. Indeed if the difference between women who<br />

have benefitted from a microcredit and those who have not is not very high (amongst<br />

company creators, the percentage of women who went through higher education is of 52.8%<br />

and 50% amongst microcredit beneficiaries), this difference is much more significant<br />

amongst men (45.2% compared to 39.2%). Similarly, male company creators are more often<br />

in employment (57% compared to 45.5% for women) whereas women are often beneficiaries<br />

of the minimum social income or other benefits (21.3%, compared to 9.7% for men). Amongst<br />

microcredit beneficiaries, the gap lessens greatly, leading us to believe that MFIs tend to<br />

favour active women and men in consistent poverty. Amongst company creators, 1 in 5<br />

women is on state benefits, compared to 1 in 10 men. Amongst microcredit beneficiaries, this<br />

rate is almost the same between men and women (1 in 2). Thus comparatively MFIs fight the<br />

battle against poverty and exclusion more for men than for women. There is no indication,<br />

however, that this is indeed discrimination by MFIs rather than self-selection<br />

(discrimination) by women themselves.<br />

Table 2. Funding characteristics<br />

Women Men Difference between<br />

Women and Men<br />

(t statistic)<br />

Probability<br />

for tstatistic<br />

Loan maturity (months) 25 27 -2.677 0.007***<br />

Interest rate (%) 4.65 4.39 1.741 0.082*<br />

Beneficiaries in % :<br />

- Interest free loan<br />

- Own funds<br />

- Loan subsidy<br />

- Bank loan<br />

56.1%<br />

37.8%<br />

24.4%<br />

20.1%<br />

61.4%<br />

41.9%<br />

23%<br />

23.6%<br />

-3.054<br />

-2.339<br />

0.931<br />

-2.351<br />

0.002***<br />

0.002***<br />

0.352<br />

0.019**<br />

Average amount of MFIs loan (euros) 4 106 5 009 -6.666 0.000***<br />

Total need for funds (euros) 21 859 30 033 -3.271 0.001***<br />

Own resources (euros) 5 067 8 444 -2.405 0.016**<br />

Average amount of supplementary bank<br />

loan (euros)<br />

9 340 12 812 -2.421 0.016**<br />

Losses (%) 2.6% 3.7% -1.7 0.089*<br />

Monthly available income (euros) 1 147 1 114 0.835 0.404<br />

*** Differences between men and women are significant at the .01 level.<br />

** Differences between men and women are significant at the .05 level.<br />

* Differences between men and women are significant at the .1 level.


10<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

The total amount of women’s projects is on average lower than that of men by almost<br />

40%, which corresponds exactly to the gap between both sexes’ complementary bank funds<br />

(Table 2). It is on the own funds level that the gap is the greatest (- 67%). Women meet their<br />

need for funds by using relatively more microcredits. Although they borrow less, over a<br />

slightly shorter period, their lending interest rate is on average higher 4 , which can in part be<br />

explained by the fact that men benefit more often from interest free loans.<br />

Beneficiaries of a micro-loan are two times less likely to have access to bank credit<br />

than the average company creator (20.1% of women and 23.6% of men compared to 45% and<br />

43% respectively). It is interesting to note that women have a guarantee fund (FGIF),<br />

managed by France Active since 2002, in order make their access to bank credit easier. This<br />

fund guarantees loans between 5,000 and 48,000 Euros. It appears to be useful since, in our<br />

sample, only 0.17% of women had a loan higher than this guaranteed limit, compared to 8.3%<br />

of men.<br />

Table 3. Project characteristics<br />

Legal structure (%):<br />

- Limited liability company<br />

- Sole ownership<br />

- Private limited company under<br />

sole ownership<br />

Business sector (%):<br />

- Retail trade<br />

- Personal service<br />

- Services for firms<br />

- Building industry<br />

- Farming<br />

- Catering<br />

- Craft industry<br />

Women Men<br />

29<br />

59.3<br />

11.7<br />

35.8<br />

40.8<br />

6.6<br />

1.2<br />

2.4<br />

7.8<br />

5.4<br />

43.7<br />

43.7<br />

12.6<br />

30.2<br />

25.4<br />

7.6<br />

16.9<br />

6.4<br />

7.5<br />

5.9<br />

In accordance with other surveys of company creators in France, but in other<br />

industrialised countries also, more than three quarters of women are to be found in the trade<br />

sector or among service providers for private individuals. Men are found in a lot more<br />

sectors, including the construction sector, agriculture, or service providers for businesses.<br />

Despite the fact that self-employment has often been presented as an opportunity for women,<br />

particularly in terms of autonomy, personal development and professional progress, studies<br />

confirm that women reproduce a certain sectoral segregation. According to Hugues (1999),<br />

because they do not have enough capital and contacts, and because they are more involved in<br />

domestic work and in children’s education, women work in “peripheral economic niches”,<br />

such as the retail trade or in personal service. These highly competitive sectors with low<br />

barriers to entry have low profit margins. In contrast, men’s work is more diversified, in<br />

trade, services to businesses, in the construction sector, or in transport.<br />

Women choose legal structures that are more adaptable and that need less personal<br />

funds. Almost 60% of them thus opt for a sole ownership, where the borrower is liable for<br />

his/her debts on his/her personal assets, as opposed to 43.7% of men. The same proportion<br />

of men choose a limited liability company (43.7% of all projects, against 29% for women).<br />

The legal status that is chosen is generally correlated with the business sector.<br />

The univariate analysis of male and female microcredit borrowers revealed several<br />

significant differences in firm and owner characteristics. Notably, we found a significantly<br />

4 This confirms the results of S. Coleman (2000) who suggests that higher interest rates are associated with smaller<br />

loans and female borrowers.


11<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

lower amount of microcredit for women compared with men. We will now carry out a<br />

multivariate analysis in order to explain these male/female differences.<br />

IV. Multivariate Analysis<br />

We estimate the microcredit supply’s determinants by using an OLS regression with<br />

fixed effects to take into account the structural specificities of the different <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

institutions we studied (Table 4). As we have seen, the impact of gender on the ability to<br />

borrow money can be linked to two types of considerations. The first is due to an indirect<br />

effect: women borrow less because they have less personal assets, less experience, and<br />

because they choose activities that require less investment (financial and personal). The<br />

second is more direct: the funding differences cannot be attributed to these previous factors,<br />

in that case, there is a “gender effect” (Verheul and Thurik, 2000).<br />

The estimated equation takes the following form:<br />

Y = a + b(Woman) + c(Borrower’s characteristics) + d(Project’s characteristics) +<br />

e(Funds’ characteristics) + it +<br />

The « Woman » variable is a dummy variable that specifies whether the borrower is a<br />

woman. If the differences in the microcredit’s amount can be explained by the borrower’s<br />

characteristics (other than sex) or by the project’s characteristics (its size, business sector,<br />

supplementary funds), “Woman’s” b coefficient should not be statistically significant.<br />

The borrower’s characteristics that are taken into account are age, experience, ethnic<br />

background, level of studies, monthly income level and occupational status (employee,<br />

corporate manager, unemployed for less or more than one year, beneficiary of minimum<br />

social income or other benefits, other). We also introduced the squared age so that any<br />

potential nonlinearities linked to age could be taken into account. The project’s<br />

characteristics are its amount, the business sector and the type of project (creation, buyout or<br />

development of a business). Lastly, the fund’s characteristics are the availability and amount<br />

of supplementary funds (own funds, bank credits, financial assistance). The results are shown<br />

in Table 4, the description of the variables can be found in annex 1. Only the variables<br />

significantly different from zero are presented.


5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Table 4: Fixed-effects (within) regression: key factors when determining the amount of the micro-loans<br />

Total Women Men<br />

Number of obs = 1967<br />

R-sq: within = 0.3506 between = 0.9204<br />

overall = 0.6065<br />

F(12,1952) = 87.81 Prob > F = 0.0000<br />

Number of obs = 1052<br />

R-sq: within = 0.2969 between = 0.8340<br />

overall = 0.5072<br />

F(8,1041) = 54.95 Prob > F = 0.0000<br />

Number of obs = 3005<br />

R-sq: within = 0.3264 between = 0.9216<br />

overall = 0.5753<br />

F(12,2994) = 111.41 Prob > F = 0.0000<br />

Coefficient Std. Err t P>|t| Coefficient Std. Err t P>|t| Coefficient Std. Err t P>|t|<br />

Amount of microloan<br />

Age 10.64191 4.362547 2.44 0.015 14.94929 5.79719 2.58 0.010<br />

Woman -435.0353 87.09972 -4.99 0.000<br />

In a couple 205.809 109.8166 1.87 0.061<br />

Studies -81.60762 36.46281 -2.24 0.025 -134.8779 48.48184 -2.78 0.005<br />

Social income -230.3135 91.6653 -2.51 0.012 -319.6723 122.2647 -2.61 0.009<br />

Corporate manager 993.5678 165.2209 6.01 0.000 1052.008 250.325 4.20 0.000 830.4972 209.4064 3.97 0.000<br />

Employee 1173.831 199.3277 5.89 0.000 1242.429 284.1027 4.37 0.000 1073.815 259.3915 4.14 0.000<br />

Total need for<br />

.0298955 .0009016 33.16 0.000 .0201704 .0012003 16.80 0.000 .0353175 .0012122 29.14 0.000<br />

funds<br />

Interest-free loan 419.6197 92.78907 4.52 0.000 413.3332 127.3234 3.25 0.001 377.885 123.1045 3.07 0.002<br />

Subsidy .0636409 .024661 2.58 0.010 .1290228 .0343701 3.75 0.000<br />

CHR 866.8528 158.5225 5.47 0.000 1333.996 220.0649 6.06 0.000 699.4961 208.9495 3.35 0.001<br />

Construction<br />

462.939 130.2347 3.55 0.000 499.1256 142.1787 3.51 0.000<br />

sector<br />

Private limited<br />

company under 1637.492 272.5753 6.01 0.000 2101.54 410.4276 5.12 0.000 1439.377 349.371 4.12 0.000<br />

sole ownership<br />

Creation loan 663.8548 87.83886 7.56 0.000 656.5705 122.2172 5.37 0.000 668.8918 114.4661 5.84 0.000<br />

Constant 2807.345 252.7671 11.11 0.000 2347.985 130.8641 17.94 0.000 2808.616 335.1736 8.38 0.000<br />

F(4, 1041) = 180.78 Prob > F = 0.0000 F(4, 1952) = 186.33 Prob > F = 0.0000<br />

F(4, 2989) = 321.86 Prob > F =<br />

0.0000<br />

F test all u_i=0<br />

12


13<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

The multivariate analysis reveals that the amount of the microcredit increases<br />

with the age of the borrower, his/her level of studies and if the borrower is a man.<br />

Social and professional status is also important. The loan will be of a greater amount<br />

if the borrower is an employee or already a corporate manager at the time of the loan<br />

whereas the loan will be of smaller amount if the borrower receives social incomes.<br />

The other significant variables have to do with the project: some sectors (such as<br />

cafes, hotels, restaurants, or the construction sector), or legal structures (private<br />

limited company under sole ownership) require higher microcredit funds. The<br />

amount of the micro loan will be greater if the project is of greater importance (this<br />

amount will also be correlated to supplementary funds, personal assets or bank loan),<br />

if it benefits from financial assistance (subsidy, interest-free loan) and if it funds the<br />

creation of a business (i.e. if it does not buyout or plan to develop an already existing<br />

business).<br />

The regression was also done separately for men and women in order to<br />

evaluate whether the amount of the loan was determined by different reasons<br />

depending on the borrower’s sex. The first result is that the borrower’s personal<br />

characteristics are of little significance for women, whereas age, level of studies and<br />

marital status are key factors for men. Another interesting result is that the micro<br />

loan’s amount will be directly correlated to the amount of the financial assistance<br />

(subsidy) that will have been obtained by women, yet for men, this variable is never<br />

significant 5 . This seems to confirm the usefulness of help directed specifically at<br />

women and therefore, implicitly, that women are penalised in their access to funds.<br />

Because the gender variable is significant in the general equation, and despite<br />

the fact that the borrower’s characteristics and his/her project and financial plan are<br />

taken into account, it seems to confirm the existence of discrimination against<br />

women on the part of <strong>microfinance</strong> institutions. This result, however, is based on a<br />

strong hypothesis: that all of the other characteristics of the individual and of the<br />

project have indeed been taken into account. As in previous studies, gender<br />

discrimination is difficult to demonstrate empirically due the existence of several<br />

factors which make the isolation of gender difficult. Empirical studies are possibly<br />

subjected to a “missing variable error”. However, our research is based on credit files<br />

given to us by microcredit institutions. So we included in our estimations all the<br />

objective information that these institutions had. The data of our econometric<br />

estimates are therefore relatively exhaustive. More subjective information could not<br />

be taken into account however, such as the way a banker perceives his/her client,<br />

which often results from a face to face meeting. Indeed, during an interview, a banker<br />

can assess his/her client’s ease and the size of his/her social capital (is he/she part of<br />

a charity network, what is the level of education of those around him, does he/she<br />

know other corporate managers…).<br />

In order to confirm our econometric results and test the hypothesis of missing<br />

variable error (that can lead to biased estimates and inappropriate conclusion about a<br />

gender effect), we estimated the same equation to determine the amount of the<br />

supplementary bank credit (Table 5). This estimate can be used for comparison<br />

(control group). We estimated the key factors that determine the amount of the bank<br />

credit that supplements the micro-loan by using the same explanatory variables, in<br />

order to determine whether the gender variable is still significant.<br />

5 Even if access to subsidies does not vary statistically depending on sex (cf. table 2).


14<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Table 5: Fixed-effects (within) regression: key factors when determining<br />

the amount of the bank credit<br />

Amount of bank<br />

credit<br />

Coefficient Std. Err t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]<br />

Woman 490.5896 684.2657 0.72 0.473 -851.0766 1832.256<br />

Employee 5151.505 1497.375 3.44 0.001 2215.544 8087.467<br />

Amount of<br />

personal assets<br />

1.432151 .0208851 68.57 0.000 1.391201 1.473102<br />

Subsidy -.3942381 .200375 -1.97 0.049 -.787121 -.0013551<br />

CHR 4563.054 1283.631 3.55 0.000 2046.189 7079.919<br />

Trade 1245.48 704.3989 1.77 0.077 -135.662 2626.622<br />

limited liability<br />

company<br />

6712.486 1442.23 4.65 0.000 3884.649 9540.322<br />

Buyout loan 3393.275 752.204 4.51 0.000 1918.4 4868.151<br />

Constant -1688.588 558.2627 -3.02 0.003 -2783.195 -593.9805<br />

Number of obs. = 3076 R-sq: within = 0.6261 between = 0.9959 overall =<br />

0.7296<br />

F(8,3064) = 641.44 Prob > F = 0.0000<br />

F test that all u_i=0: F(4, 3064) = 6.51 Prob > F = 0.0002<br />

A noteworthy finding is that the gender variable is not significant in<br />

determining the amount of bank loans. This indicates that bank lenders do not<br />

discriminate against women in providing access to a loan. Of all the characteristics of<br />

the borrower, this loan depends only on the borrower’s social status (regularity of<br />

monthly income due to working as an employee) and on his/her personal assets.<br />

Moreover the bank loan will be higher for buyouts, for limited liability companies,<br />

and in the retail trade and the cafe hotel and restaurant sectors. Moreover financial<br />

assistance becomes a substitute for bank loans, which thus turns into supplementary<br />

funding.<br />

Finally, we created representative sub-samples. Another way to deal with the<br />

challenge of disentangling the effect of gender from the effects of variables associated<br />

with gender is to use a “matching technique” (Fabowale et al. 1995). One factor that<br />

may explain why women experience greater difficulty in obtaining credit on average<br />

is their lower level of personal assets. We first study a representative sub-sample 6 ,<br />

based on an identical amount of personal assets in the men’s group and in the<br />

women’s group (this amount is of 13,800 euros). Women’s need for loans is slightly<br />

lower than men’s (with a total project of 45,373 euros for women, 47,622 for men,<br />

that is – 4.5%) whereas the amount of the microcredit is lower by 10% (6,125 euros<br />

compared to 6,781). To compensate for this, women borrow a little more from banks<br />

(higher amount and indebtedness rate) 7 . A second representative sub-group, made<br />

up of 2,152 men and 952 women, was created on the basis of a project with identical<br />

average amount (25,400 euros). Again, the amount of microcredits obtained by<br />

women is lower than men’s by 9% (10,570 euros compared to 11,591, bearing in mind<br />

that the difference becomes statistically significant at 1%). Differences in personal<br />

assets (on average -2.2%) or in monthly income are not significant. In terms of<br />

supplementary funds, women obtain more bank loans (+ 9.6%) and a little more<br />

6 Of borrowers with non-zero personal assets.<br />

7 The gap is smaller between men and women for borrowers without own funds. Within this group,<br />

women have projects that are lower than men’s by 10.9% and their microcredit amount is lower by 13%.


15<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

financial assistance (+ 3.3%). In the latter case, however, the difference is not<br />

significant.<br />

Whether in developing countries or in industrialised countries, the different<br />

studies show that women face the same difficulties in their projects to create their<br />

own business. Some of these difficulties are linked to women as individuals (their<br />

skills, their experience, their self-confidence), some are family-related (couple<br />

relationships, children), but there are also economic and financial difficulties: poor<br />

access to outside funds, activities that generate little income, weight of domestic<br />

chores (Johnson 2000). It appears from our study that women are somewhat more<br />

penalised that men in their access to microcredit, and that personal differences or<br />

differences in projects cannot, of themselves, explain such a gap. Yet women, maybe<br />

because they are subjected to a greater selection than men, have a much higher<br />

repayment rate than men. But a high repayment rate tells us nothing of the<br />

difficulties that have to be faced (women often attach more importance to the credit<br />

relationship than to their capacity to generate a decent monthly income, which can<br />

jeopardise the business’s survival. The credit will have been paid back in the agreed<br />

conditions, but the business will have disappeared). Moreover women tend to<br />

reproduce, in the creation of their business, the poor perspectives they had as<br />

employees.<br />

Microfinance institutions are more interested, as traditional banking<br />

institutions, by the credit relationship and the likelihood of repayment of the loan<br />

rather by the type of business that is being financed (business sector, legal<br />

structure…). In other words, MFIs don’t really promote women’s enterprise beyond<br />

credit and implicitly they will encourage, more particularly, women to stay in<br />

traditional activities. However MFIs may not be considered like other finance<br />

<strong>org</strong>anisations, they also have to have a role of counsel and support. More than the<br />

supply of funds, MFI can also play an important part in informing and guiding<br />

women towards more profitable projects. Generally speaking, mechanisms that<br />

enable women to accumulate more personal assets and to have access to larger loans<br />

should also be considered, as studies have shown that these will enable the funding of<br />

more profitable and viable projects. The undercapitalisation of new firms has a long<br />

term implication for business performance.


Bibliography<br />

16<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Allen I.E., Langowitz N., Minniti M. (2007), 2006 Report on Women and<br />

Entrepreneurship, Global Entrepreneurship Monitor.<br />

Anderson S., Carter S., Shaw E. (2001), Women's Business Ownership: A<br />

Review of the Academic, Popular and Internet Literature, Small Business Service<br />

Research Report: RR002/01, August.<br />

Bird B., Brush C. (2002), A Gendered Perspective on Organizational Creation,<br />

Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice, Vol. 26, n° 3, 41-65.<br />

Boden R.J., Nucci A. (2000), On the Survival Prospect of Men’s and Women’s<br />

New Business Ventures, Journal of Business Venturing, vol. 15, 347-362.<br />

Brana S., Jegourel Y. (2007), Breadth and depth of French <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

outreach: an evaluation, mimeo.<br />

Brush C.G. (1992), Research on Women Owners: Past Trends, a New<br />

Perspective and Future Directions, Entrepreneurship Theory & Practice, Vol. 16,<br />

Issue 4, Summer, 5-30.<br />

Buttner E.H., Rosen B. (1988), Bank loan officers’ perceptions of the<br />

characteristics of men, women, and successful entrepreneurs, Journal of Business<br />

Venturing, vol. 3, Issue 3, Summer, 249-258.<br />

Carter S., Shaw E. (2006), Women's Business Ownership: recent research and<br />

Policy Developments, Report to the Small Business Service, November.<br />

Carter S, Lam W., Shaw E., Wilson F. (2007), Gender, Entrepreneurship, and<br />

Bank Lending, the Criteria and Processes used by Bank Loan Officers in Assessing<br />

Applications, Entrepreneurship Theory & Practice, Vol. 31, Issue 3, May, 427-444.<br />

Cheston S. (2007), Just the Facts, Ma’am’: Gender Stories from unexpected<br />

Sources with Morals for Microfinance in ADA Dialogue « Microfinance and Gender:<br />

New contributions to an Old Issue », n° 37, May, 13-25.<br />

Coleman S. (2000), Access to Capital and Terms of Credit: A comparison of<br />

Men- and Women- Owned Small Businesses, Journal of Small Business<br />

Management, July, vol. 38, n°3, 37-52.<br />

Commission européenne (2007), Rapport sur l’égalité entre les hommes et les<br />

femmes, février.<br />

Danes S.M., Stafford K., J.T.-C. Loy (2007), Family Business Performance:<br />

The effects of gender and management, Journal of Business Research, Vol. 60, Issue<br />

10, October, 1058-1069.<br />

Fabowale L., Orser B., Riding A. (1995), Gender, Structural Factors, and<br />

Credit Terms between Canadian Small Businesses and Financial Institutions,<br />

Entrepreneurship Theory & Practice, Summer, vol. 19, Issue 4, 41-65.<br />

Fay M. (1993), Gender bias and the availability of business loans, Journal of<br />

Business Venturing, Vol. 8, Issue 4, July, 363-376.<br />

Fernando J. (ed.) (2006), Perils and Prospects of Microfinance, London,<br />

Routledge.<br />

Goetz A, Gupta R.S. (1996), Who Takes the Credit? Gender, Power and<br />

Control Over Loan Use in Rural Credit Programs in Bangladesh, World Development,<br />

vol. 24, n° 1, 45-63.<br />

Guérin I., Palier J. (2006), Microfinance and the Empowerment of Women:<br />

Will the Silent Revolution Take Place, Finance and the Common Good / Bien<br />

Commun, Issue n° 25, Autumn, 76-82.<br />

Hughes, K. D. (1999), Gender and Self-Employment in Canada: Assessing<br />

Trends and Policy Issues, Ottawa: Canadian Policy Research Networks, CPRN<br />

n°W/04.


17<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Johnsen G.J., McMahon R.G.P. (2005), Owner-manager Gender, Financial<br />

Performance and Business growth amongst SMEs from Australia’s Business<br />

Longitudinal Survey, International Small Business Journal, Vol. 23, n° 2, 115-142.<br />

Johnson S. (2000), Gender Impact assessment in <strong>microfinance</strong> and<br />

microenterprise: why and how, Development in practice, Vol. 10, N°1, February. 89-<br />

93.<br />

Johnson S. (2005), Gender relations, Empowerment and Microcredit: Moving<br />

on from a Lost Decade, The <strong>European</strong> Journal of Development Research, vol. 17, n°<br />

2, June, 224-248.<br />

Langowitz N., Minniti M. (2007), The Entrepreneurial Propensity of Women,<br />

Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, Vol. 31, Issue 3, May, 341-364.<br />

Mayoux L. (2007), Not only Reaching, but also Empowering Women: Ways<br />

Forward for the Next Microfinance Decade, in ADA Dialogue « Microfinance and<br />

Gender: New contributions to an Old Issue », n° 37, May, 35-60.<br />

Marlow S., Patton D. (2005), All Credit to Men? Entrepreneurship, Finance<br />

and Gender, Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice, Vol. 29, n° 6, 717-735.<br />

Riding A., Swift C. (1990), Women business owners and terms of credit: some<br />

empirical findings of the Canadian experience, Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 5,<br />

Issue 5, September, 327-340.<br />

Underwood T. (2006), Women and Microlending in Western Europe, EMN<br />

Working Paper, n° 2, April.<br />

Verheul et Thurik, 2000 Start-Up Capital : Differences between male and<br />

Female Enntrepreneurs ‘Does Gender Matter ?’, ERIM Report Series Research in<br />

Management, March.<br />

Watson J. (2002), Comparing the Performance of Male- and Female-<br />

Controlled Businesses: Relating Outputs to Inputs, Entrepreneurship Theory and<br />

Practice”, vol. 26, n°3, Spring, 91-100.<br />

Watson J., Robinson S. (2003), Adjusting for risk in comparing the<br />

performance of male-and female –controlled SMEs, Journal of Business Venturing,<br />

Vol. 18, n°6, 773-788.


18<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Annex 1. Descriptive statistics for dependant and independent<br />

variables<br />

Number of observations = 3866 Period = 2000-2006<br />

Dummy variables<br />

Variable Mean Standard Errors<br />

Bank loan<br />

Yes = 1 Non = 0<br />

Sex<br />

Woman = 1 Man = 0<br />

Ethnic background<br />

French = 1 Other =0<br />

Marital situation<br />

single, widow, divorced = 1<br />

Married, in a couple = 0<br />

Social status<br />

Minimum social income =1 if not=0<br />

Social benefits=1 if not =0<br />

Unemployed (< 1 year)=1 if not =0<br />

Unemployed (> 1 year) if not =0<br />

Corporate manager=1 if not =0<br />

Employee =1 if not =0<br />

Other<br />

Own funds<br />

Yes=1 No=0<br />

Experience<br />

Yes=1 No=0<br />

Purpose of the loan<br />

New business=1 if not =0<br />

Repurchase=1 if not =0<br />

Expansion=1 if not =0<br />

Activity<br />

Craft industry=1 if not=0<br />

Services for firms=1 if not =0<br />

Services for private households=1 if not<br />

=0<br />

Retail trade=1 if not =0<br />

Building industry=1 if not =0<br />

Farming=1 if not =0<br />

Catering=1 if not =0<br />

Level of education<br />

University (Master’s degree - PhD)=1<br />

University (Bachelor’s degree)=2<br />

Baccalaureate=3<br />

Secondary school=4<br />

Junior school=5<br />

0.297<br />

0.346<br />

0.821<br />

0.488<br />

0.346<br />

0.134<br />

0.207<br />

0.104<br />

0.091<br />

0.068<br />

0.05<br />

0.413<br />

0.615<br />

0.578<br />

0.276<br />

0.145<br />

0.057<br />

0.073<br />

0.308<br />

0.321<br />

0.114<br />

0.05<br />

0.077<br />

3.34<br />

0.44<br />

0.476<br />

0.383<br />

0.499<br />

0.476<br />

0.340<br />

0.405<br />

0.305<br />

0.288<br />

0.252<br />

0.218<br />

0.492<br />

0.499<br />

0.494<br />

0.447<br />

0.352<br />

0.232<br />

0.26<br />

0.461<br />

0.467<br />

0.317<br />

0.218<br />

0.265<br />

1.136


Quantitative variables<br />

Variable Average Gap<br />

Age (years) 37 18 - 70<br />

19<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Microcredit amount (euro) 4 801 100 - 38 000<br />

Bank credit amount (euro) 12 689 0 - 785 000<br />

Total need for funds (euro) 28 719 100 - 1 516 868<br />

Personal assets amount (euro) 7 581 0 - 1 417 776<br />

Monthly income (euro) 1 127 35 - 9 100<br />

Loan’s maturity (months) 26.4 1 - 92<br />

Interest rate (%) 4.2 0 - 23


20<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Making <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> more sustainable – lessons from<br />

Britain<br />

Dr. Karl Dayson, executive director, Pål Vik, research assistant, Bob<br />

Paterson, visiting research fellow, Anthony Salt, research associate<br />

Community Finance Solutions, University of Salford, Crescent House, Room 214,<br />

Salford M5 4WT, United Kingdom<br />

Tel: +44 0161 295 2827 E-mail: k.t.dayson@salford.ac.uk<br />

Website: www.communityfinance.salford.ac.uk<br />

Abstract: This paper identifies and analyses best practice in promoting sustainable<br />

<strong>microfinance</strong> institutions (MFIs) based on an in-depth analysis of five UK MFIs. The<br />

study focused on the effectiveness of MFI partnerships, staff efficiency and loan<br />

portfolio profitability, which previous research suggests are the key pathways to<br />

enhance sustainability. Situated between the Western <strong>European</strong> model of statesubsidised<br />

enterprise support and the Eastern <strong>European</strong> sector focusing on scale and<br />

efficiency, the UK <strong>microfinance</strong> sector may offer important lessons in balancing<br />

efficiency and social impact.<br />

We conducted a benchmarking study of five UK MFIs, part of which we analysed and<br />

modelled the past and future performance of their loan portfolios, their partnerships,<br />

and the way in which their staff members spent their time and the processes and<br />

structures driving this time-use.<br />

We found that the MFIs are still some way away from covering all their costs with<br />

income generated from their core activity of lending. The results of the analysis of the<br />

loan portfolio suggest that they can increase their sustainability considerably through<br />

charging interest rates which more closely reflect the costs of delivery and by<br />

<strong>org</strong>anising staff to maximise loan officer exposure to potential customers. The degree<br />

to which the MFIs can boost the sustainability of their operations depend on their<br />

starting point (i.e. interest rates charged, initial loan officer productivity), product<br />

mix and cost structure. We argue that the funders and policy-makers can aid the<br />

sector move towards greater sustainability through ensuring that loan capital is<br />

available to underpin portfolio growth and through providing development grants to<br />

stage-manage productivity increases.<br />

We hope that our findings and recommendations will enable funders and policymakers<br />

support the UK and <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> sector in a more effective and<br />

progressive manner. In addition to highlighting best-practice in MFIs operations, our<br />

hope is that the research instigates greater cooperation and sharing of best practice<br />

across the sector. Building on the experience of sharing data and practices as part of<br />

the research project, the five participating MFIs are now cooperating on a wider<br />

range of issues through a newly established user group.<br />

Key Words: Microfinance, operational sustainability


Introduction<br />

21<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Achieving sustainability is today a key aim of the global <strong>microfinance</strong> movement<br />

alongside its social and economic objectives. Sustainability is seen as important<br />

because sustainable Microfinance Institutions (MFIs) “meet their goals now without<br />

harming their ability to meet their goals” in the future (Schreiner, 2000, p.425)<br />

There are two specific definitions of sustainability: operational and financial.<br />

Operational sustainability refers to the ability of an MFI to cover its costs with<br />

income from its core activities (i.e. fee and interest rate income from its loan<br />

portfolio), whilst financial sustainability refers to the ability to cover its costs if it had<br />

to raise 100% of its loan portfolio through recycling existing funds and through<br />

borrowing funds at the market rate (CGAP, 2003; CDFA, 2006).<br />

Sustainability rose to prominence in research and policy debates following the<br />

theoretical and empirical critique embodied in the research by a group of researchers<br />

at the Ohio State University on subsidised agricultural programmes operating in<br />

Latin America in the 1960s and 1970s (Adams, 1972; Von Pischke and Adams, 1980).<br />

Their criticism of these programmes was twofold. First, they argued that the<br />

concessionary terms of lending distorted the potential economic and social impacts<br />

by enticing higher-income individuals to take out the loans. Second, their limited<br />

capacity to reuse loan capital, owing to high cost/income ratios, translated into short<br />

life-spans stifling ability to capitalise on staff and institutional learning.<br />

However, the emphasis placed on sustainability of <strong>microfinance</strong> programmes by<br />

policy-makers and practitioners across the expanded <strong>European</strong> Union has been<br />

highly uneven. The Eastern <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> sector has generally followed the<br />

current <strong>microfinance</strong> orthodoxy in focusing on sustainability, profitability and scale<br />

(Bateman, 2003; Hartarska et al, 2006). The non-bank MFI sector in Central and<br />

Eastern Europe as a whole is self-sustaining according to figures from the<br />

Microfinance Information Exchange (2006, 2007).<br />

Conversely “Western <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> has…a strong focus on social inclusion<br />

and pays less or almost no attention to its profitability” (Evers and Jung, 2007, p.10).<br />

For reasons of a difficult and little developed market place, sectoral immaturity and<br />

the presence of subsidies, there has not been a considerable move towards<br />

sustainability (Evers and Jung, 2007; Guichandut and Underwood, 2007). This is<br />

evidenced by the apparent lack of consolidation of the sector in Germany where the<br />

number of institutions is increasing whilst the number of customers is decreasing<br />

(Evers and Lahn, 2007). Instead, there has been a general focus on the costeffectiveness<br />

of <strong>microfinance</strong> compared to state-run welfare programmes.<br />

The UK <strong>microfinance</strong> model finds itself somewhere between the Eastern and Western<br />

<strong>European</strong> models. As in the case of Western Europe, there is a strong focus on social<br />

inclusion, as evidenced by the assignation of funding based on reaching target<br />

groups, predominantly very low-income households. On the other hand, the UK<br />

government has stressed the importance of scaling up MFIs to serve excluded<br />

communities, especially in the case of personal financial services (HM Treasury,<br />

2007). Moreover, indicators relating to financial sustainability, such as minimum<br />

interest rates for personal loans and maximum loan delinquency rates, are also often<br />

attached to grant funding.<br />

Situated between the Western <strong>European</strong> model of state-subsidised enterprise support<br />

and the Eastern <strong>European</strong> sector focusing on scale and efficiency, the UK<br />

<strong>microfinance</strong> sector may thus offer important lessons in balancing efficiency and<br />

social impact. This paper analyses the degree to which the UK sector has managed to


22<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

pursue operational sustainability, whilst meeting social targets tied to funding,<br />

through an in-depth benchmarking study of five UK MFIs.<br />

Previous research into the UK MFI sector has identified three pathways of improving<br />

financial and operational sustainability (Forster et al, 2004; New Economics<br />

Foundation, 2004; Dayson, 2005; Dayson, 2006): staff productivity and efficiency,<br />

effective partnerships (to reduce costs and increase client base) and an appropriately<br />

mixed loan portfolio. Hence, in this paper we conducted a benchmarking study of five<br />

UK MFIs, as part of which we analysed and modelled the past and future<br />

performance of their loan portfolios, their partnerships, and the way in which their<br />

staff members spent their time and the processes and structures driving this timeuse.<br />

We found that the MFIs in our sample are still some way away from covering all their<br />

costs with income generated from their core activity of lending. The results of the<br />

analysis of the loan portfolio suggest that they can increase their sustainability<br />

considerably through charging interest rates which more closely reflect the costs of<br />

delivery and by <strong>org</strong>anising staff to maximise loan officer exposure to potential<br />

customers.<br />

The remainder of the paper is <strong>org</strong>anised as follows. The second section outlines the<br />

methodology and the participating MFIs. The third presents the findings of the<br />

analysis of staff productivity, partnership effectiveness and profitability of loan<br />

portfolio. The fourth concludes and discusses the implications of the findings for<br />

<strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong>.<br />

Methodology<br />

The case study methodology applied for this study consisted of three components.<br />

First, we analysed the use of time by MFI staff members, recorded through a<br />

timesheet complted daily for a three week period by the staff members, in order to<br />

ascertain the staff productivity and efficiency. In addition to recording minutes spent<br />

on tasks (e.g. loan interviews, opening up of loan accounts), loans officers were asked<br />

to record number of loan applicants seen. Based on the latter data, we were able to<br />

make estimations about annual loan officer productivity, which in turn fed into the<br />

loan portfolio analysis. We also conducted qualitative interviews with 16 staff<br />

interviews to explore the drivers and causes of time use.<br />

Second, in order to analyse the effectiveness and nature of partnerships formed by<br />

the MFIs, their partner <strong>org</strong>anisations filled in an online questionnaire. This<br />

questionnaire contained questions concerning three potentially performanceenhancing<br />

aspects of partnerships: increasing customer base (through referrals and<br />

marketing), transferring costs and accessing funding.<br />

Finally, to determine the profitability and sustainability of the portfolio of products<br />

and activities of the participating MFIs, the following data was collected and analysed<br />

for business loans (including social enterprise loans), personal loans and home<br />

improvement loans for the financial year of April 2006 to March 2007:<br />

- Size of loan book (number of loans, value of loans);<br />

- Income from interest rates and fees;<br />

- Staff and overhead costs for delivery;<br />

- Loans written off, arrears and capital at risk;<br />

- Capital available to lend (including sources of funding)<br />

Five MFIs covering England were included in the study (Table 1).


Number of<br />

employees (FT<br />

positions)<br />

Total value<br />

OLP (£ ‘000)*<br />

Financial<br />

products (% of<br />

OLP)<br />

Loans granted<br />

by product<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Table 1: The MFIs studied<br />

MFI A MFI B MFI C MFI D MFI E<br />

PL (74)<br />

BL (26)<br />

PL: 1262<br />

BL: 78<br />

10 12 5 11 5<br />

951’ 202’ 554’ 444’ 520’<br />

PL (37)<br />

BL (34)<br />

SEL (29)<br />

PL: 202<br />

BL: 46<br />

SEL: 2<br />

23<br />

PL (54)<br />

BL (46)<br />

PL: 310<br />

BL: 23<br />

PL (58)<br />

BL (41)<br />

HIL (1)<br />

PL: 562<br />

BL: 41<br />

HIL: 4<br />

HIL (100)<br />

HIL: 89<br />

Other services SP DMA .. DMA ..<br />

Branches<br />

3 2 2 2 1<br />

Source: Loan portfolio data provided by the MFIs for the financial year of April 2006 to<br />

March 2007<br />

Notes: * Assessed on March 31 2007<br />

Abbreviations: PL = Personal loans, BL = Business loans, SEL = Social Enterprise Loan, HIL<br />

= Home Improvement Loans, SP = Savings products, DMA = Debt and Money Advice, FT =<br />

Full-time, OLP = Outstanding loan portfolio<br />

The MFIs differ in terms of their business strategies and product portfolio. MFI E is a<br />

specialised home improvement loan lender and was included as a point of reference<br />

for long-term performance of the product and for administrative and technical<br />

requirements for introducing the home improvement loan.<br />

MFI A specialises in personal finance and has since April 2007 stopped offering<br />

business loans. Conversely, MFI B, MFI D and, to a lesser extent, MFI C offer a wide<br />

range of services to households, social enterprises and small businesses, including<br />

advice and home improvement loans. Nevertheless, because personal loans<br />

constituted the single greatest number of loans and greatest value of the outstanding<br />

loan portfolio for MFIs A to D, we will in this paper refer to these MFIs as personal<br />

lending MFIs.<br />

Findings<br />

This section presents the main findings of the case study research and is divided into<br />

three sections. The first discusses the findings from the analysis of the use of time<br />

among MFI employees. The second analyses the effectiveness of partnerships, whilst<br />

the third examines the level of sustainability of the loan portfolio.<br />

Staff productivity<br />

Increasing the efficiency and productivity of MFI employees is a potentially powerful<br />

determinant of sustainability, by the number of loans a loan officer can make and the<br />

amount of time the <strong>org</strong>anisations can spend on reducing loan losses through<br />

monitoring and debt collection.<br />

In order to ascertain the level of staff productivity and efficiency staff members filled<br />

in a daily timesheet over a three-week period. In total, 48 out of 51 MFI staff<br />

members submitted timesheets (Table 2), and semi-structured interviews were<br />

conducted with 16 staff members from the 5 MFIs.


24<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Table 2: Participating staff members<br />

MFI A MFI E MFI C MFI D MFI B Total<br />

Total staff 7 5 6 11 6 48<br />

Admin 2 1 1 2 1 7<br />

Lenders 3 3 3 6 3 18<br />

Management 2 1 2 3 1 2 10


25<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

The data was weighted according to the normal distribution of staff across the staff categories<br />

to ensure that non-participating staff members did not skew the results. Because MFI E is a<br />

specialised home improvement loan provider, the tables displays the averages for the<br />

personal lending MFIs, and much of the analysis will centre on differences and similarities in<br />

the use of time between these MFIs.<br />

Table 3 displays the weighted timesheet data according to activity by MFI for all staff<br />

members. Each activity consists of numerous tasks. For example, making loans consist of<br />

loan interviews, reviewing application, issuing of loan and loan administration. A key<br />

distinction made is the distinction between the time spent on sustaining activities – tasks not<br />

easily linked to the provision of financial products – vs. time spent on core activities directly<br />

linked to the provision and monitoring of loans.<br />

Table 3: Proportion of time spent by all staff by MFI (% of productive time)<br />

MFI A MFI B MFI C MFI D<br />

Average<br />

score<br />

MFI E<br />

Loan<br />

enquiries<br />

7.1 2.5 8.0 3.5 5.3 0.4<br />

Money<br />

advice<br />

1.9 0.3 0.8 0.1 0.8 0.5<br />

No shows<br />

2.7 0.1 0.0 1.0 1.0 0.1<br />

Making<br />

loans<br />

31.4 33.7 21.9 29.2 29.1 39.1<br />

Month-end<br />

reports<br />

4.3 1.7 4.6 2.2 3.2 1.3<br />

Servicing<br />

loans<br />

2.7 2.4 5.1 3.8 3.5 0.7<br />

Delinquency<br />

control<br />

7.9 10.0 13.3 12.6 11.0 2.6<br />

Promotional<br />

activities<br />

3.5 9.7 11.5 17.0 10.4 14.4<br />

Office<br />

management<br />

36.6 36.9 33.9 29.1 34.1 37.1<br />

Other<br />

activities<br />

1.9 2.7 0.9 1.5 1.8 3.8<br />

Notes: Reported as percentages based on weighted data<br />

Source: Timesheets submitted by MFI employees for the period 25.06.07-13.07.07<br />

The MFIs appear to spend their time on four activities. First, tasks relating to office<br />

management constitute the single biggest activity for all the personal lending MFIs with the<br />

exception of MFI D. There seems to be a certain minimum time a MFI has to dedicate to<br />

general office tasks (a minimum of 5%), staff meetings (around 5%), queries (4-6%) and<br />

report preparation (3-5%). Second, tasks involved in making a loan constitute the second<br />

most time-consuming category, hovering between 20 and 40% of productive time. Once the<br />

loan has been made, relatively little time is dedicated to servicing loans (2-5%). This reflects<br />

the insistence among MFIs on servicing the loans through automated bank transfers. Third,<br />

once a client falls in arrears with their payments, the MFIs display considerable willingness<br />

to invest time in chasing arrears (8-13% for the personal lending MFIs). The emphasis on<br />

delinquency control appeared to be driven by a fear that inaction on part of the MFI could<br />

foment a non-payment culture among borrowers.<br />

Finally, MFIs also appear to invest extensive time on promotional activities (external<br />

meetings, presentations, outreach activities, marketing, liaising with partners and<br />

networking). With the exception of MFI A, the MFIs spend between 10 and 17% of their time<br />

on promotional activities. MFI D spends the greatest proportion of its time on promotional<br />

activities largely because it has a dedicated outreach worker. Because the MFIs in the sample


26<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

are still dependent on granted loan capital and other forms of subsidies, they must invest<br />

time on maintaining contracts and relations with public and private sector <strong>org</strong>anisations.<br />

This may explain the time invested in external relationship management and promotional<br />

activities.<br />

Table 4 shows how the administrators across the participating MFIs spend their time.<br />

Table 4: Proportion of time spent by admin staff by category (% of productive<br />

time)<br />

MFI A MFI B MFI C MFI D<br />

Average<br />

score<br />

MFI E<br />

Loan<br />

enquiries<br />

4.9 4.5 11.5 14.9 9.0 0.0<br />

Money<br />

advice<br />

0.0 1.6 3.4 0.0 1.3 0.0<br />

No shows<br />

0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0<br />

Making<br />

loans<br />

19.8 2.9 21.4 9.9 13.5 2.8<br />

Month-end<br />

reports<br />

1.5 3.2 3.7 3.3 2.9 9.5<br />

Servicing<br />

loans<br />

13.7 15.5 16.0 23.2 17.1 6.7<br />

Delinquency<br />

control<br />

10.7 0.0 15.7 11.9 9.6 0.0<br />

Promotional<br />

activities<br />

0.0 0.0 8.9 0.3 2.3 0.0<br />

Office<br />

management<br />

40.3 69.9 19.4 36.5 41.5 71.0<br />

Other<br />

activities<br />

9.1 2.4 0.0 0.0 2.9 10.0<br />

Notes: Reported as percentages based on weighted data<br />

Source: Timesheets submitted by MFI employees for the period 25.06.07-13.07.07<br />

Here there is more variation than could be observed for the MFIs as a whole. This variance<br />

centres principally on the extent to which the administrators get involved in loan provision,<br />

dealing with loan enquiries and giving applicants money advice. On the one hand there are<br />

MFIs whose administrative staff specialise almost purely on office management tasks, with<br />

very limited involvement in the MFI’s core activities. This is very much the case of MFI B,<br />

where the administrator spends minimal time on lending activities (with the exception of<br />

servicing loans). On the other, the administrators at some MFIs have an extensive<br />

involvement in the making, servicing and monitoring of loans, which is the case at MFI A.<br />

The rationale behind this division of labour seems to be to maximise the exposure of lending<br />

staff to clients. As we will see when looking at the timesheet data for the loans officers, the<br />

model seems to achieve that, as MFI A lending staff spend more time than the loans officer of<br />

any other MFI on dealing with potential customers.<br />

The two above-mentioned divisions of labour may only work in larger <strong>org</strong>anisations. The<br />

administrator in MFI C, the smallest MFI in the sample, has a non-specialised role getting<br />

involved in all aspects of the operation of the MFI.


Table 5 displays the use of time among managers across the MFIs.<br />

27<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Table 5: Proportion of time spent by management by category (% of productive<br />

time)<br />

MFI A MFI B MFI C MFI D Average<br />

score<br />

MFI E<br />

Loan<br />

enquiries<br />

1.6 1.2 3.8 0.7 1.8 0.0<br />

Money<br />

advice<br />

0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0<br />

No shows<br />

0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0<br />

Making<br />

loans<br />

17.2 11.4 12.1 3.2 11.0 3.4<br />

Month-end<br />

reports<br />

12.4 4.0 7.7 6.1 7.6 1.3<br />

Servicing<br />

loans<br />

0.0 0.9 4.9 0.1 1.5 0.0<br />

Delinquency<br />

control<br />

7.4 1.7 7.6 0.9 4.4 0.3<br />

Promotional<br />

activities<br />

6.9 25.8 13.9 35.1 20.4 25.0<br />

Office<br />

management<br />

54.5 54.0 48.3 47.5 51.1 64.4<br />

Other<br />

activities<br />

0.0 1.0 1.7 6.4 2.3 5.6<br />

Notes: Reported as percentages based on weighted data<br />

Source: Timesheets submitted by MFI employees for the period 25.06.07-13.07.07<br />

One of the factors distinguishing the MFIs is the degree of management involvement in<br />

making loans. On the one hand, the management of MFI D and MFI E only have very limited<br />

involvement in making loans. This appeared to be related to reliance on contractual income<br />

and the complexity of funding arrangements. On the other, there are managers who are much<br />

more involved in the loan process, particularly MFI A and MFI C. In the case of the former,<br />

the managers spend more than 6% of their time on interviews alone, which is more than the<br />

managers in all the other MFIs combined. This is largely a reflection of the <strong>org</strong>anisational<br />

culture of MFI A. All the <strong>org</strong>anisation’s activities are centred on increasing the loan book<br />

through seeing potential clients. To be able to do that, managers cover for loans officers on<br />

leave and generally offer extensive lending support.<br />

Finally, we turn to the use of time among the loan officers across the participating MFIs<br />

(Table 6). The loans officers play a crucial role in a MFI as they have the most extensive<br />

contact with the client base and often build relations with customers, vital in informing<br />

lending decisions and in limiting defaults and loan losses.


28<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Table 6: Proportion of time spent by lending staff by category (% of<br />

productive time)<br />

MFI A MFI B MFI C MFI D<br />

Average<br />

score<br />

MFI E<br />

Loan enquiries<br />

11.8 2.6 13.4 1.7 7.4 0.6<br />

Money advice<br />

No shows<br />

Making loans<br />

Month-end<br />

reports<br />

Servicing loans<br />

Delinquency<br />

control<br />

Promotional<br />

activities<br />

Office<br />

management<br />

Other activities<br />

4.0 0.1 0.8 0.1 1.3 0.7<br />

5.6 0.1 0.1 1.7 1.9 0.1<br />

46.5 54.4 38.5 48.9 47.1 58.4<br />

0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0<br />

0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0<br />

7.2 17.4 21.6 18.9 16.3 3.9<br />

2.8 2.9 8.7 6.9 5.3 12.5<br />

21.8 18.8 16.9 19.7 19.3 21.5<br />

0.3 3.7 0.0 2.1 1.5 2.2<br />

Notes: Reported as percentages based on weighted data<br />

Source: Timesheets submitted by MFI employees for the period 25.06.07-13.07.07<br />

Making loans constitutes the single most time-consuming activity for loans officers. Three<br />

out of the four personal lending MFIs spend around 20% on delinquency control. This<br />

activity generally involves monitoring daily, weekly or monthly bank reports of direct debits,<br />

and acting accordingly by calling, paying visits to or sending letters to the clients. The lending<br />

staff are to varying degrees supported by administrators and managers in monitoring and<br />

acting upon non-payment.<br />

Lending staff at MFI A spend considerably less time on delinquency control than the other<br />

MFIs because of its automated arrears monitoring system. This system requires loan officers<br />

to make a call to delinquent clients, whilst all other aspects of the delinquency control<br />

(further follow-ups and debt collection) are dealt with by administrative and management<br />

staff.<br />

This time-saving arrears reporting system combined with the way in which support and<br />

management staff are <strong>org</strong>anised enables lending staff at MFI A to focus on seeing potential<br />

clients. Personal loans officers at MFI A spend around 45% of their time dealing directly with<br />

clients compared to approximately 30% (MFI C), 25% (MFI B), 15% (MFI D) and less than<br />

10% (MFI E) for the other MFIs. The MFI A model centre on maximising the loans officers’<br />

exposure to clients by assigning most other tasks not directly linked to the loan interviews to<br />

the administrators and to the management.<br />

The estimates on number of loans per full-time loan officer suggest that this enables MFI A<br />

interview and process 40% more loan applicants compared with the second-most productive<br />

MFI (Table 7).


<strong>Annual</strong> # of<br />

loans process<br />

per FT loan<br />

officer<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Table 7: Personal loans officer productivity<br />

Average<br />

MFI A MFI B MFI C MFI D<br />

score<br />

440 308 205 253 320<br />

Notes: Estimated based on number of loan applicants seen during timesheet exercise<br />

Assumes 60% success rate based on data from MFI B<br />

Source: Timesheets submitted by MFI employees for the period 25.06.07-13.07.07<br />

Three factors appear to explain the variation in loan officer productivity. First, the number of<br />

applicants a loans officer can interview is conditional on the availability of appropriate<br />

meetings rooms. In the case of MFI B, two loans officers and two debt advisors share one<br />

meeting room, limiting the number of loan applicants a loans officer can see in the course of<br />

a working day. Second, the data also suggest that a high proportion of repeat business is<br />

conducive for loan officer productivity as they are considerably less costly to process and<br />

generally less risky. MFI A which displayed the greatest loan officer productivity also had the<br />

greatest proportion of repeat clients: 56% of loans issued in the financial year of 2006/2007<br />

were to repeat customers, compared to 7% (MFI B), 33% (MFI D) and 52% (MFI C). Finally,<br />

the timesheet data suggest that there is a link between the proportion of productive time<br />

spent on seeing clients and loan officer productivity as depicted in Figure 1.<br />

% loan officer time spent on direct customer contact<br />

40.00<br />

35.00<br />

30.00<br />

25.00<br />

20.00<br />

<br />

Figure 1: Direct customer contact and loan officer productivity<br />

MFI C<br />

<br />

MFI D<br />

200.00 300.00 400.00<br />

<br />

29<br />

MFI B<br />

MFI A<br />

TIME = -1.33 + 0.09 * PROD<br />

R-Square = 0.69<br />

Number of loans made per FT loan officer per year<br />

In summation, MFI A which puts the greatest emphasis on maximising the time loans<br />

officers spend on interviewing, by involving administrators and managers in offering lending<br />

support, also processes the greatest number of loans per full-time loan officer position.<br />

Further, our findings suggest that part of maximising lending staff exposure to potential<br />

customers may also lie in outsourcing administrative aspects of arrears control and possibly<br />

other areas to external companies.


Partnership effectiveness<br />

30<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Like the productivity of staff, effective partnerships can improve the sustainability of a MFI,<br />

by increasing its client base through referrals and marketing. In addition, the willingness of a<br />

partner <strong>org</strong>anisation to donate loan capital and buy other service from a MFI is determined<br />

by how effective they perceive the partnership to be.<br />

In order to measure the effectiveness of these partnerships, 27 partner <strong>org</strong>anisations filled in<br />

an online questionnaire (Table 8).<br />

Housing<br />

association<br />

Debt advice<br />

agency<br />

Bank, build<br />

society<br />

Local<br />

government<br />

RDAs<br />

Charity<br />

Business<br />

advice<br />

Other<br />

Total<br />

Table 8: Partner <strong>org</strong>anisations by MFI<br />

MFI A MFI B MFI C MFI D MFI E Total<br />

1 3 .. 3 0 7<br />

0 0 .. 2 0 2<br />

1 2 .. 1 0 4<br />

0 0 .. 3 6 9<br />

0 1 .. 0 0 1<br />

0 0 .. 1 0 1<br />

0 1 .. 0 0 1<br />

0 2 .. 0 0 2<br />

2 9 .. 10 6 27<br />

Source: Online questionnaire filled in by MFI partner <strong>org</strong>anisations September and October<br />

2007<br />

Local government and housing associations constitute the majority of MFI partners. In this<br />

sample, the majority of local councils are cooperating with the MFIs in relation to the<br />

provision of home improvement loans. For housing associations, partnerships with the MFI<br />

sector is seen as a key strategy in reducing the risk of households falling behind on their rent<br />

by offering an alternative to their tenants to pawnbrokers and doorstep lender who often<br />

charge very high interest rates.<br />

The MFIs and their partners cooperate in numerous ways (Chart 1, N = 27).


%<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

Chart 1: Type of partnerships<br />

Funding Make referrals Receive referrals Service Marketing Product<br />

development<br />

Source: Online questionnaire filled in by CDFI partner <strong>org</strong>anisations September and October 2007<br />

31<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Joint tendering Other<br />

The majority of partner <strong>org</strong>anisations refer clients to the MFI, market the MFI’s product to<br />

its clients and provide the MFI with funding. About a third of the partner <strong>org</strong>anisations fund<br />

the MFIs in exchange for a service, which in all cases refers to home improvement loans.<br />

Broadly speaking we can draw a simple typology of the different types of partnerships. First,<br />

there are the partnerships which MFIs form with arms-length funders. Second, there are the<br />

<strong>org</strong>anisations which fund a MFI in exchange for a service, typically local governments<br />

funding MFIs for the delivery of home improvement loans. Finally, there are the<br />

relationships between MFIs and so-called peer <strong>org</strong>anisations, which provide non-financial<br />

services to low-income households, such as debt and money advice. These <strong>org</strong>anisations<br />

include job centres, debt advisory agencies, business links and housing associations. These<br />

relationships are typically limited to referrals and basic marketing.<br />

In total, 18 out of the 27 partnerships were referral-based, 15 of which were local government,<br />

housing associations and money advice agencies. Most partner <strong>org</strong>anisations made less than<br />

one referral per week and most of the referrals from local government are made in relation to<br />

home improvement loans.<br />

The way in which partner <strong>org</strong>anisations perceive the MFI and the services it provides is likely<br />

to be important for their willingness to invest time and resources in a partnership, enhancing<br />

its effectiveness. Overall the survey data suggest that most partner <strong>org</strong>anisations had very<br />

favourable views of the MFIs in terms of trustworthiness and reliability. However, the<br />

partner <strong>org</strong>anisations expressed greater doubt about the effectiveness and meaningfulness of<br />

the partnerships themselves.<br />

Loan portfolio analysis<br />

So far we have looked at two key levers in enhancing operational sustainability –<br />

partnerships and staff productivity – and the extent to which the MFIs make use of them. But<br />

how sustainable are the MFIs?<br />

Chart 2 shows the degree to which the MFIs are operationally sustainable. Specifically, using<br />

their most recent audited accounts, we calculate the total earnings (fees and interest income,<br />

and bank interest earned or paid) as a percentage of total overheads (staff, overhead and<br />

governance related costs). The average column refers to the average for the personal lending<br />

MFIs (i.e. it excludes MFI E).


Operational sustainability (%)<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

Chart 2: Overall operational sustainability<br />

32<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

MFI A MFI B MFI C MFI D Average MFI E<br />

Source: Audited accounts for the calendar year of 2006 or for the financial year of 2006/2007<br />

The MFIs are some way away from covering their costs exclusively through the income<br />

generated from their loan portfolios. The average for the personal lending MFIs is below 40%<br />

and the most sustainable MFI has an operational sustainability of just above 60%. However,<br />

compared to other UK MFIs, the MFIs in the sample perform reasonably well. The average<br />

operational sustainability for the personal lending MFIs surpass those of Aspire (32%)<br />

(Forster et al, 2006) and Street UK (7%) (New Economics Foundation, 2004). The average<br />

operational sustainability ratio is also on par with the average of UK MFIs (36%) (Brown and<br />

Nissan, 2007).<br />

MFI A and MFI E are the most sustainable MFIs in that they are able to cover around 60% of<br />

their income through interest rates, fees and bank interest earned. The low level of<br />

operational sustainability of MFI B is largely explained by its reliance on contractual income<br />

to fund its money advice programme.<br />

So far we have examined the current level of operational sustainability of the MFIs. However,<br />

given that the personal lending MFIs are relatively young <strong>org</strong>anisations at an early stage in<br />

their development trajectory, a more interesting question may be how far along the<br />

sustainability continuum they can progress over the next few years. Therefore, we project<br />

several possible future development trajectories for the MFIs.<br />

Drawing on the basic cost structure (staff, governance and office costs), loan and product<br />

portfolio mix (average amounts, number of loans, split repeat/new loans, interest rates, fees<br />

etc), and capital and funding streams (liabilities, financial expense, funding contracts) of the<br />

MFIs for the financial year of 2006/2007, we made projections about the future growth and<br />

performance of the MFIs for the following seven financial years: 2007/2008 through to<br />

2013/2014. Furthermore, we also made some assumptions about the future behaviour of the<br />

<strong>org</strong>anisations and the climate in which they operate. We assume an annual growth in loans<br />

issued of 10% for personal loans and a range of growth rates for business loans and home<br />

improvement loans, depending on funding arrangements (see Dayson et al, 2008 for further<br />

details). We also assume a 5% annual increase in the value of loans and an annual inflation<br />

rate of 4%. Furthermore, we have applied a standard bad debt ratio of 15% (10% for repeat<br />

clients) for both business and personal loans, and a ratio of 0.5% for home improvement<br />

loans. In addition to these base budget projections (as now), we hypothesise that the MFIs<br />

can alter their level of sustainability by increasing loan officer productivity (increased


33<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

productivity), raising the interest rates charged (increased interest rates) and by adding<br />

higher-value loans (with HIL). Chart 3 shows the average operational sustainability ratio for<br />

the MFIs under each of these scenarios.<br />

Operational sustainability<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

Chart 3: Enhancing sustainability<br />

06/07 07/08 08/09 09/10 10/11 11/12 12/13 13/14<br />

As now Increased interest rate Increased productivity With HIL Best practice<br />

Generally, providing that they can ensure portfolio growth at the rates given above, the MFIs<br />

appear to be gradually enhancing their ability to cover their operating costs with income from<br />

fees and interest rates in all scenarios including the scenario “as now.” The results of the<br />

financial modelling indicate that over time the MFIs are improving their performance even if<br />

they make no changes to the way they operate (as now), providing they can grow their<br />

personal loan portfolio at 10% and keep their business loan portfolios constant. That said the<br />

MFIs can make considerable improvements by using any of the abovementioned levers.<br />

Raising interest rates to the highest charged in the peer group and introducing an up-front<br />

administration fee on personal loans constitute the single-greatest improvement to<br />

operational sustainability. In particular, the introduction of an upfront administration fee for<br />

personal loans has positive implications for operational sustainability. The advantage with<br />

such a fee is that it is not affected by arrears and as such can give a disproportionate boost to<br />

income. For MFIs A and D, who operate with an upfront administration fee of 5 and 3% of<br />

the loan value respectively, the administration fee income constitutes around 40% of total<br />

activity earnings. Raising loan officer productivity to the highest level among the<br />

participating MFIs (400 loans per year per full-time loan officer) also makes a considerable<br />

contributing increasing operational sustainability on average by nearly 10% within the first<br />

year.<br />

Finally, adding a higher-value, low-risk loan product in the form of the home improvement<br />

loan can make a significant contribution to the long-term sustainability of the MFI sector as<br />

shown in the graph above. The home improvement loan is offered to low-income home<br />

owners as a means of improving the standard of their housing. Many local authorities fund<br />

such schemes through paying subscription fees and subsidising interest rates, making them<br />

an attractive option for customers and MFIs alike.<br />

We assume that the MFIs make 41 home improvement loans at an interest rate of 8% and at<br />

an average value of £5,500 in their first year of operation (2009/2010). As suggested by<br />

Chart 2 even a modest higher-ticket loan portfolio can make a considerable contribution to<br />

raising sustainability, assuming a 10% annual growth. However, the effectiveness of each of<br />

the levers outline above for the individual MFIs depends on the starting point of the MFIs


34<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

(i.e. interest rates charged, current loan officer productivity) and product mix (i.e. a high<br />

reliance on contractual income negatively affects the operational sustainability ratio).<br />

So far we have assumed that the MFIs have access to interest free capital for on-lending.<br />

However, a potentially very important barrier for the expansion and future sustainability of<br />

the sector may be the availability of lending capital. Currently the MFI sector is not able to<br />

offer deposit services, except on an agency basis, and even if they were, it is questionable the<br />

extent to which the funds raised through medium and long-term savings products would be<br />

able to significantly contribute towards loan capital.<br />

Chart 4 displays the size of the gap in funding (expressed in £‘000) to support a 10% annual<br />

growth in their personal loan portfolio using best-practice approaches (e.g. in terms of<br />

interest rates, productivity and home improvement loans), once the MFIs have recycled their<br />

existing loan capital (i.e. the opening balance at the beginning of 2007/2008). Here we<br />

exclude the capital requirements for the home improvement loan given that there are<br />

particular funding arrangement in which it is given that the MFI borrows to on-lend part of<br />

the home improvement loans.<br />

£'000<br />

700<br />

600<br />

500<br />

400<br />

300<br />

200<br />

100<br />

0<br />

Chart 4: Future capital requirements<br />

07/08 08/09 09/10 10/11 11/12 12/13 13/14<br />

MFI A MFI B MFI C MFI D<br />

The chart reveals that even if the MFIs were to implement best practice there would still be a<br />

considerable funding gap. Already in Year 1 (2007/2008), MFI A experiences a six-digit<br />

funding gap, whilst MFI C has a shortfall of £75,000. The figures for MFI B are similar to<br />

MFI C, whilst MFI D first experiences funding shortages in year 2011/2012 because of its<br />

slower projected volume growth in personal loans and considerable reserves.<br />

The future capital requirements for MFI A are considerably greater than those of the other<br />

MFIs, because of the much greater scale of its operation. For example, according to our<br />

projections, MFI A will lend out more than £1 million in personal loans alone in year 1<br />

(2007/2008) and over £3.5 million in year 7 (2013/2014). In comparison, MFI C will make<br />

loans (business and personal loans) for less than £350,000 in year 1 and less than £900,000<br />

in year 7. This would suggest that a recapitalisation strategy based exclusively on recycling<br />

existing loan capital is not a viable means of supporting the expansion of the sector. The<br />

sector remains dependent on raising funds through grants, contract income and through<br />

borrowing loan capital.


Conclusions<br />

35<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Over three decades since Adams, Von Pischke and their colleagues at Ohio State University<br />

highlighted serious problems with the theoretical and institutional underpinnings of the<br />

subsidised and concessionary agricultural lending programmes in Latin America, the notion<br />

that MFIs should strive towards full sustainability is today part of the development<br />

orthodoxy. Situated between the Western <strong>European</strong> model of state-subsidised enterprise<br />

support and the Eastern <strong>European</strong> sector focusing on scale and efficiency, the UK<br />

<strong>microfinance</strong> sector may offer important lessons in balancing efficiency and social impact. In<br />

this study, we have drawn on the findings of an in-depth benchmarking analysis of five UK<br />

MFIs to highlight lessons for the <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> market on reaching sustainability<br />

whilst targeting the lower end of the market.<br />

Our findings suggest that the MFIs are still some way away from covering all their costs<br />

exclusively through customer fees. The most sustainable MFIs in the sample are able to cover<br />

just over 60% of their costs through interest rates, fees and bank interest earned. The results<br />

of the financial modelling indicate that over time the MFIs are improving their performance<br />

even if they make no changes to the way they operate. However, the MFIs can, depending on<br />

their starting point and mix of products, make considerable improvements by adjusting<br />

interest rates and fees, and by increasing productivity. However, we also found that high<br />

overhead costs relative to activity earnings (interest income from bank deposits, income from<br />

interest and fees earned) can act as a break on sustainability.<br />

The financial sensitivity analysis of future capital requirements and different models of<br />

recapitalisation suggest that raising loan capital purely through recycling existing funds is an<br />

unviable strategy to fund future expansion of the MFIs in the sample. Already in the first year<br />

of operation without granted or borrowed loan capital, the most sustainable MFIs experience<br />

considerable funding shortages.<br />

There also appears to be a set of norms for maximising staff efficiency and productivity. We<br />

found a strong relationship between the time the lending staff spent on direct customer<br />

contact and loan officer productivity. Provided there is sufficient demand for the products of<br />

the MFI, by <strong>org</strong>anising the non-lending in such a way to maximise the exposure of the<br />

lending staff and by allowing non-lending staff to step in for interviews when necessary, the<br />

MFI can raise the loan officer productivity considerably. Further, our findings further<br />

suggest that part of maximising lending staff exposure to potential customers also lies in<br />

outsourcing administrative aspects of arrears control and possibly other areas to external<br />

companies. In terms of outsourcing administrative parts of arrears control, it does not appear<br />

to affect arrears levels.<br />

Finally, we also found that the loan officer productivity is crucially linked to the proportion of<br />

repeat clients. The MFI which displayed the greatest loan officer productivity also had the<br />

greatest proportion of repeat clients. Repeat business involves lower transactions costs and<br />

generally constitutes a smaller risk for the MFI. It is considered crucial therefore to design<br />

products and procedures in a way which entices customers to come back.<br />

Based on the above findings, we suggest that there are certain structural and process-related<br />

changes which are likely to have a particularly positive impact on the sustainability of the<br />

sector. First, the MFIs can charge interest rates which more closely reflect the costs involved<br />

in providing loans. Second, the sector can take steps to maximise the lending staff’s exposure<br />

to potential customers, namely re<strong>org</strong>anise staff to increase time frontline staff spend on<br />

seeing potential customers and implement time-saving outsourcing mechanisms. Finally, the<br />

MFIs can capitalise on links with other MFIs to enhance innovation and costs, through<br />

sharing best-practice and start-up costs and franchising certain products.<br />

For their part, and in light of the likely shortages of loan capital of the sector in the future, the<br />

funders and policy-makers can aid the sector move towards greater sustainability through


36<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

ensuring that loan capital is available to underpin portfolio growth and through providing<br />

development grants to stage-manage productivity increases.<br />

However, the potential for becoming more sustainable is not uniform across the sector, but is<br />

likely to depend on the starting point of the MFI (i.e. interest rates charged, initial loan<br />

officer productivity), its product mix and its cost structure. Moreover, given the heterogeneity<br />

of the expanded EU <strong>microfinance</strong> sector and of the context in which they operate, the<br />

effectiveness and feasibility of these levers may not be uniform. There are in particular two<br />

contextual factors which condition MFIs’ ability to make use of these levers. First, the<br />

regulatory framework, especially caps on interest rates, may limit the possibility of closing<br />

the gap between delivery costs and customer fees. German law, for example, prohibits<br />

charging very high or usurious interest rates (Mark and Tilleßen, 2007). Second, the depth of<br />

the market and the level of cost-sensitivity of the customers will determine the MFIs ability to<br />

reach scale and set customer fees resembling costs. The Microfinance Information Exchange<br />

(2006) notes that, in Central and Eastern Europe a highly cost-sensitive customer base<br />

prevents the <strong>microfinance</strong> sector from increasing interest rates.<br />

Perhaps, most importantly the case studies indicate the difficulty faced by MFIs operating<br />

within sophisticated financial services environments. All the MFIs were seeking to reach<br />

clients that mainstream providers were reluctant or unable to serve, or compete with highcost<br />

sub-prime suppliers. In both cases this reduces the potential market, while increasing<br />

the delivery costs. For example, clients have to be persuaded to move away from entrenched<br />

sub-prime providers, which involves time and an element of financial education. In such a<br />

market MFIs are likely to remain niche players and even the most efficient will struggle to<br />

reach and maintain sustainability. The question this poses for policymakers is whether the<br />

scoio-economic benefit of MFIs is of greater priority than MFIs sustainability. It is the<br />

reverse problem that Adams and Von Pischke highlighted among agricultural programmes:<br />

does pursuing financially sustainable interventions result in placing borrowers in a riskier<br />

financial situations through ‘real cost’ pricing. Thereby undermining social inclusion policies.<br />

We suspect that a <strong>European</strong> approach to MFIs role in economic inclusion resides somewhere<br />

between the high cost policy driven interventions of the 1970s and the supply side solutions<br />

of the 1990s and early twenty-first century.


Bibliography<br />

37<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Adams, D. W. (1972). Agricultural Credit in Latin America: A Critical Review of External<br />

Funding Policy, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 53(2), 163-172.<br />

Bateman, M. (2003). ‘New wave’ <strong>microfinance</strong> institutions in south-east Europe: towards a<br />

more realistic assessment of impact, Small Enterprise Development 14(3), 56-65.<br />

CDFA (2006). CDFA Glossary of Community Development Finance. February, 2006.<br />

CGAP (2003). Microfinance Consensus Guidelines – Definitions of Selected Financial<br />

Terms, Ratios, and Adjustments for Microfinance. Washington: CGAP.<br />

Dayson, K. (2005) Are community finance institutions doing too much? Paper presented at<br />

the Institute of Small Business Entrepreneurs conference, Blackpool.<br />

Dayson, K. (2006) Assessing the performance of <strong>microfinance</strong> providers in the UK, Paper<br />

presented at the <strong>European</strong> Microfinance conference, Budapest.<br />

Evers, J. and Jung, M. (2007). Status of <strong>microfinance</strong> in Western Europe – an academic<br />

review. EMN Issue Paper, March 2007.<br />

Evers, J. and Lahn, S. (2007). Status of Microlending in Germany: An Empirical Survey of<br />

Programmes in 2006, In KfW Bankengruppe (Eds.), Microfinance in Germany and Europe<br />

(pp 33-52). Frankfurt: KfW Bankengruppe.<br />

Forster, S., Lederman, E., Mayshak, J., and Mercer, T. (2006). Aspire – Microloans for<br />

Business: Operational and Funding Lessons for the Future of Microfinance in the UK. A<br />

report for the Esmée Fairbairn and CDFA submitted April 2006.<br />

Guichandut, P. and Underwood, T. (2007). Microcredit in the <strong>European</strong> Union: An Overview,<br />

In KfW Bankengruppe (Eds.), Microfinance in Germany and Europe (pp 33-52). Frankfurt:<br />

KfW Bankengruppe.<br />

Hartarska, V., Caudill, S. B and Grooper, D. M. (2006). The Cost Structure of Microfinance<br />

Institutions in Eastern Europe and Central Asia. William Davidson Institute Working Paper<br />

Number 809, January 2006.<br />

HM Treasury (2007). Financial inclusion: an action plan for 2008-11, December 2007.<br />

Microfinance Information Exchange (2006). Benchmarking Microfinance in Eastern Europe<br />

and Central Asia 2005, November 2007<br />

Microfinance Information Exchange (2007). Benchmarking Microfinance in Eastern Europe<br />

and Central Asia 2006, November 2007.<br />

New Economics Foundation (2004). Lessons from Experience: An Evaluation of Street<br />

(UK). A report for the Esmée Fairbairn Foundation submitted 2004.<br />

Schreiner, M. (2000). Ways Donors Can Help the Evolution of Sustainable Microfinance<br />

Organizations, Savings and Development 23(4), 375-405.<br />

Von Pischke, J. D. and Adams, D. W. (1980). Fungibility and the Design and Evaluation of<br />

Agricultural Credit Projects, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 62(4), 719-726.<br />

Mark, K. and Tilleßen, P. (2007). Microfinance in Germany, In KfW Bankengruppe (Eds.),<br />

Microfinance in Germany and Europe (pp 33-52). Frankfurt: KfW Bankengruppe.


38<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Microfinance as a <strong>European</strong> policy issue – policy images and venues<br />

Michael Unterberg, research assistant, EVERS & JUNG GmbH<br />

Deichstraße 29<br />

D-20459 Hamburg<br />

Tel: (+49.) 40 3680968 31 E-mail: Michael.unterberg@eversjung.de<br />

Website: www.eversjung.de<br />

Abstract<br />

This paper aims at identifying the major driving forces behind the rise of the issue of<br />

<strong>microfinance</strong> as a policy issue in the EU from the late 90s up to the announcement of an<br />

<strong>European</strong> action plan on microcredit in 2006. The paper was influenced by the experiences of<br />

the author working in several EU-funded projects on the development of policy measures to<br />

foster <strong>microfinance</strong> in the EU.<br />

The research is designed as a policy analysis on agenda-setting processes at EU level. It draws<br />

heavily on recent political science approaches to EU agenda-setting and policy making that<br />

focus on the impact of epistemic communities, policy entrepreneurs and issue networks. At<br />

the core of the research done lies an extensive analysis of public available EU documents<br />

dealing with the issue of <strong>microfinance</strong>/-credit. Processes that were not possible to reconstruct<br />

through document analysis were discussed in interviews with key actors, like Ms. Nowak,<br />

president of the EMN and Mr. Mulfinger, former Head of Unit at DG Enterprise.<br />

Additionally, an online survey was conducted in 2007 to gather an exploratory picture of the<br />

attitudes in the <strong>microfinance</strong> community toward <strong>microfinance</strong> as a policy issue.<br />

The agenda-setting process is analysed in four distinctive steps or phases: issue initiation,<br />

issue specification, issue expansion and issue entrance. The main focus lies on assessing the<br />

involvement of <strong>microfinance</strong> experts in the phase of issue specification and their role in<br />

shaping policy images of the issue of <strong>microfinance</strong>.<br />

The main findings of the research support the thesis of an important role of the EMN and its<br />

president Ms. Nowak in the process of positioning <strong>microfinance</strong> as a policy issue at EU-level.<br />

They also show that the <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> community was successful in shaping the<br />

dominant policy image of <strong>microfinance</strong> at the EU-level to include aspects of social inclusion.<br />

Another key result is the finding that the success of <strong>microfinance</strong> as a policy issue at EU-level<br />

was strongly connected to the availability of accessible policy venues, mainly thanks to the<br />

OMC. Since the new action plan on microcredit demarks a new step in the issue career of<br />

<strong>microfinance</strong> it will be interesting to see how future changes in the EU modes of governance<br />

will affect accessibility to the EU policy-making for the <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> community.<br />

Subheadings:<br />

Introduction<br />

Policy initiation in the EU and agenda setting<br />

Agenda-setting in the EU<br />

A framework for analysis<br />

Actors and policy venues<br />

Two routes of agenda-setting in the EU<br />

Microfinance in Europe – problem structures and policy implications<br />

The policy community of <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

The route of <strong>microfinance</strong> in the <strong>European</strong> Union<br />

Issue initiation<br />

Issue specification<br />

Issue expansion<br />

Issue entrance<br />

Conclusion<br />

Keywords: EU, <strong>microfinance</strong>, agenda-setting, policy making


Introduction<br />

39<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Since the first mentioning of <strong>microfinance</strong> in Europe as a policy issue in the early Nineties the<br />

issue quickly rose to more prominence in different policy arenas of EU-politics. Right now<br />

the issue of developing <strong>microfinance</strong> in Europe can be found on the agendas of many DGs of<br />

the Commission, covering a wide range of social and economic policy implications. With the<br />

announcement of a <strong>European</strong> initiative on micro-credit in 2007 the issue finally has reached<br />

the formal institutional agenda of the <strong>European</strong> Union.<br />

From the viewpoint of political science this process of policy initiation is a phenomenon that<br />

needs further explanation. Why is it that an instrument originally developed to fight poverty<br />

in the underdeveloped countries of the south gets this much attention from EU policymakers?<br />

This is even more the question since, despite some success stories, the <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

sectors of Western Europe have up to now failed to prove that <strong>microfinance</strong> programs can<br />

operate in an effective and self-sustaining way in an environment characterized by highly<br />

developed financial sectors and welfare systems (see Evers/Lahn/Jung 2007). Although the<br />

situation is different in Central and Eastern Europe, where <strong>microfinance</strong> providers were able<br />

to realise considerable growth rates since the late Nineties, mostly due to weak financial<br />

sectors and economic reconstruction (see Foster et al 2003), it seems unlikely that the<br />

development of broad policy activity on the EU-level can be mainly explained with regulative<br />

pressure from emerging <strong>microfinance</strong> sectors in Europe.<br />

Therefore this paper tries to identify the main drivers that started and shaped the process of<br />

policy initiation on the issue of <strong>microfinance</strong> in the <strong>European</strong> Union. Furthermore the paper<br />

examines how institutional and temporal corridors of opportunity in the ‘low policy’ area of<br />

<strong>European</strong> politics influenced the involvement of actors at different stages and venues of the<br />

process. It is in this policy area that the governance mode of the EU has shifted markedly in<br />

the past years towards more soft and coordinated forms of governance, most noticeable with<br />

the implementation of the Open Method of Coordination (OMC) in the Lisbon process<br />

starting in 2000. Since some of these ‘new modes of governance’ allow a more direct<br />

involvement of non-state actors in the EU policy making process it seems likely, that the<br />

policy initiation process of the issue of <strong>microfinance</strong> was also influenced by this shift in<br />

institutional opportunity structures.<br />

The chosen analytical approach relies mainly on the conceptual toolbox of agenda-setting.<br />

The time period observed reaches from 1998 to 2006, when the public announcement of an<br />

EU-wide action plan on <strong>microfinance</strong> put the issue finally on the formal agenda of the EU<br />

Commission. Empirically the analysis is based on an extended analysis of public EU<br />

documents, an online survey in the <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> community and halfstandardized<br />

interviews with key actors from the community and the Commission.<br />

Policy initiation in the EU and agenda setting<br />

Based on a typology by Ripley (Ripley 1985), three different processes of policy initiation can<br />

be specified. These are: the process of problem definition, the process of agenda-setting and<br />

the process of development and specification of policy alternatives. Recent literature on<br />

policy initiation in the EU argues that these three processes can be interrelated and<br />

subsumed in a broader understanding of the concept of agenda-setting (e.g. Princen/Rhinard<br />

2006, Parrish 2003). If agenda-setting is understood this way it relates to the processes by<br />

which new issues are recognised by policy makers as well as to the ways in which those issues<br />

are (re-)defined and framed and, finally, addressed with specific policy solutions. Moreover,<br />

agenda-setting in such a broader understanding does not only concern how new issues enter<br />

the agenda, but also the ways old issues move up and down the agenda and get redefined<br />

along.


40<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Agenda-setting in this wider sense is mainly used as a concept for policy analysis at national<br />

level. Up to now it has not received much attention as a conceptual framework to analyse EU<br />

policy making. This is striking, since most of the scientific literature does characterize policymaking<br />

in the EU as a multi-venue process that offers many entrance points to actors that<br />

wish to influence the range of issues considered by EU policy makers. Agenda-setting should<br />

therefore be able to offer a valuable toolbox for the study of these processes.<br />

As applied to policy-making, the term agenda can be defined as “the list of subjects or<br />

problems to which government officials, and people outside the government closely<br />

associated with those officials, are paying some serious attention at any given point in time”<br />

(Kingdom 1995: 3-4). Cobb and Elder (Cobb/Elder 1972) draw a distinction between the<br />

systemic and the institutional agenda in political systems. As Parrish (Parrish 2003: 40)<br />

notes, in the <strong>European</strong> Union the function of a systematic agenda is carried out by the<br />

agendas of the <strong>European</strong> institutions, while the notion of an institutional agenda can be<br />

paralleled to the stage where issues are finally defined and <strong>European</strong> policies are shaped.<br />

Agenda-setting in the EU<br />

As a political system the <strong>European</strong> Union is characterized by a highly fragmented decisionmaking<br />

system with multiple avenues of policy making and many entry-points for influence.<br />

Also, the absence of a functioning mechanism of policy co-ordination and its complex multilevel<br />

system of governance create many paths for agenda-setting. This is even more the case if<br />

one considers the <strong>org</strong>anisational structure of the <strong>European</strong> Commission, the most important<br />

institution in the agenda-setting process of the <strong>European</strong> Union. It is <strong>org</strong>anised in different<br />

DGs, that are weakly coordinated administrative entities, dominated by a different policy<br />

making styles and administrative cultures (Knill 2005: 206) ii . The DGs rival constantly over<br />

the definition and the framing of issues and policy alternatives in the process of EU policymaking.<br />

Additionally, their staffs are in a sort of steady flux, making their agendas especially<br />

open for change and external influences. Conflicts and misunderstandings occur often,<br />

mostly due to missing or underdeveloped interfaces between the political and administrative<br />

level. Therefore, the <strong>European</strong> Union can be regarded as a relatively open institutional<br />

environment for agenda-setting processes. But due to the high amount of consensus needed<br />

to start decision processes, this holds not true for the whole agenda-setting process: „It may<br />

be easy to get someone at the EU level to consider an issue, but it is more difficult to get an<br />

issue high on the political agenda of the EU as a whole.“ (Princen 2007: 33)<br />

A framework for analysis<br />

For analytical purposes four elements or phases of the agenda process in political systems<br />

can be distinguished. The first phase is the phase of issue initiation or issue recognition,<br />

when the attention of policy-makers and those around them is drawn to particular problems<br />

or issues for the first time, hence allowing them to enter the agenda. This initial phase is<br />

followed by the phase of issue specification. This phase takes central stage in most studies of<br />

agenda-setting processes because the way an issue or problem is defined and demarked<br />

against other issues is an influential step for its further development on the agenda. It<br />

includes the specification of different policy alternatives and the process of linking them to<br />

the issue at hand. In the phase of issue expansion, political dynamics are at work to spread<br />

the specified issue further throughout the political system. Finally the phase of issue entrance<br />

when the issue enters the formal institutional agenda of the system concludes the agendasetting<br />

process. To build a more informed framework for analysis of the process of agendasetting<br />

in the EU the literature on national agenda-setting can be of great value. Especially<br />

two approaches are considered here, John Kingdon’s “multiple streams” approach (Kingdon


41<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

1995) and the “punctuated equilibrium” theory of Baumgartner and Jones<br />

(Baumgartner/Jones 1993).<br />

Building on Kingdon’s work on agenda setting, three major forces that drive agenda-setting<br />

processes in political systems can be identified: problems, actors and institutions. To<br />

understand the dynamics of specific agenda-setting processes it is therefore important to<br />

analyse how these forces interact. Regarding agenda-setting in the EU especially two<br />

concepts of Kingdon can be of much help to model such interactions. The first is the notion of<br />

the important role of individual ‘policy entrepreneurs’ that influence the agenda-setting<br />

process in a political system by strategically coupling problems to policies through the use of<br />

issue framing. The second is the importance of temporal limited shifts in the politics stream<br />

(so called ‚opportunity windows’), like elections or changes in the mode of governance, that<br />

produce new patterns of problem recognition and policy alternatives and therefore offer<br />

strategically minded actors opportunities for the use of coupling strategies.<br />

Despite this notion of institutional opportunity windows, Kingdons’ approach lacks further<br />

specifications of the role of institutional aspects in the process of agenda-setting. Here<br />

Baumgartner and Jones’ approach to agenda setting offers a helpful addition, as they are<br />

bringing the role of policy images and policy venues to the forefront. A policy image is<br />

considered by Baumgartner and Jones as the way an issue is simplified, (re-) defined and<br />

specified for political discussion through experts and specialists. The elements of policy<br />

images are open for manipulation and their constant development is an important part of<br />

policy making. A single issue can be attached to different policy images, which emphasize<br />

different social or political aspects of the issue or even contradict each other. Policy images of<br />

issues are always constructed to address specific policy venues, which are understood as "the<br />

institutional locations where authoritative decisions are made concerning a given issue."<br />

(Baumgartner/Jones 1993: 32). The strategic use of this attachment of policy images to policy<br />

venues is called „venue shopping“ and is seen by Baumgartner and Jones as an important<br />

option for policy entrepreneurs and other actors in the process of policy making to get an<br />

issue higher on the agenda. It is especially useful in fragmented political systems, since<br />

"[m]any venues with only vague or ambiguous constraints on their jurisdictional boundaries<br />

create opportunities for strategically minded policy entrepreneurs to shop for the most<br />

favourable locus for their policies."(Baumgartner/Jones 1993: 36). In view of the<br />

fragmentation of the <strong>European</strong> Union policy making process as well as of the Commission’s<br />

administration, the concept of venue shopping seems especially suited to be used to<br />

understand how issues are framed in a certain way to address specific policy venues in the<br />

<strong>European</strong> Union’s institutional setting. An important part of this concept is to examine how<br />

policy images of issues and problems are defined to establish the supranational <strong>European</strong><br />

level as the suited policy level to deal with them. (vgl. Princen 2007: 32).<br />

Actors and policy venues<br />

The processes of policy initiation are characterized by the importance of knowledge resources<br />

and technical expertise. In this respect, the literature on the policy making process of the EU<br />

notes that transnational networks of experts are playing an increasingly important role in<br />

many stages of the process (vgl. Richardson 2006: 5). These networks are reported to<br />

originate in scientific projects, funded by the Commission or working groups of independent<br />

non-state experts (Radaelli 1995: 171). One way to conceptualize such a network is to<br />

understand it as an ‘epistemic community’. An epistemic community is defined by Haas<br />

(Haas 1992) as a network of knowledge-based experts or groups with an authoritative claim<br />

to policy-relevant knowledge within the domain of their expertise. Members hold a common<br />

set of causal beliefs and share notions of validity based on internally defined criteria for<br />

evaluation, common policy projects, and shared normative commitments. (Haas 1992: 3).<br />

Following Zito (Zito 2001: 590f), one can assume that such networks or communities are<br />

especially important in agenda setting processes when the issue shows a high grade of<br />

uncertainty and addresses problems that are connected with accepted quantitative data sets.


42<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Additionally, most approaches to agenda-setting include individual policy entrepreneurs iii as<br />

important actors, that are able to manipulate the representation of problems and issues in<br />

the agenda-setting process and therefore to influence the decision of policy makers in a<br />

strategic way. While the agenda-setting process in the EU is in general open for policy<br />

entrepreneurs, there are also systematic barriers and obstacles that policy entrepreneurs<br />

have to overcome in order to influence the process. A striking example is the amount of<br />

possible veto-positions, especially regarding routine processes with a high number of actors<br />

involved that often exceeds the influence capabilities of individual entrepreneurs.<br />

In the fragmented multi-level system of policy making in the <strong>European</strong> Union it is possible<br />

for analytical purposes to establish a horizontal distinction between policy arenas, that<br />

feature different functional layouts and different modes of governance. In these arenas, that<br />

are connected to specific policy fields, like social policy or structural policy, processes of<br />

policy initiation can develop relatively independent of each other, therefore paralleling the<br />

notion of policy venues by Baumgartner and Jones. The interplay of activities in these policy<br />

venues is especially relevant in processes of developing policy alternatives for cross-cutting<br />

issues iv . At the level of the Commission there is also a constant need of coordination with<br />

national administrations, interest groups and external experts, who are often embedded<br />

through working groups into the processes of policy and programme formulation (Knill<br />

2005: 206/207). Non-state actors can exploit their participation in those informal arenas to<br />

influence the process of policy formation, especially regarding technical issues that are not<br />

yet routinely processed (Zito 2001: 590).<br />

Two routes of agenda-setting in the EU<br />

Princen und Rhinard have identified two routes into which agenda-setting can unfold in the<br />

EU’s institutional framework that builds on the distinction between high and low politics in<br />

the EU.<br />

The high poltics route (Princen/Rhinard 2006: 1121-1123) unfolds mainly top-down and is<br />

primarily a political route. The main driving force at the beginning of the agenda-setting<br />

process are high-ranking political figures assembled in the <strong>European</strong> Council, where the<br />

problem is recognised (issue initiation), mostly due to a focussing event, and first steps<br />

toward problem definition and issue framing takes place (issue specification). Since the<br />

<strong>European</strong> Council will normally limit itself to provide rather general principles about the<br />

issue in question. The task of further problem definition is delegated down one level to the<br />

Commission and Council of Ministers, that have to interpret the decision of the political<br />

leaders and act accordingly. So once the problem is recognised and framed, it moves outside<br />

the initial circle of policy initiators and to the institutional agendas where policy alternatives<br />

will be considered and influence from outsiders may be possible. The high politics route of<br />

agenda-setting is characterized by a high degree of political momentum stemming from the<br />

top-down initialisation. This momentum may be watered down if the technical aspects of an<br />

issue dominate the debate.<br />

The low-politics route (Princen/Rhinard 2006: 1121-1123) unfolds bottom-up and is mainly<br />

technocratic and technical. Issues do not enter the agenda due to political concern but<br />

through the technical concerns of experts and professionals working in the same area. This<br />

initiation route is rather typical to Commission and Council working groups. Issue framing in<br />

the low politics route takes part in the Commission but is much more specific and technical<br />

than in the high politics route, mostly due to the work of expert groups. Once the problem is<br />

framed it is brought to the formal agenda and goes through the decision-making process. The<br />

moving up of issues towards the institutional agenda is a difficult process, since advocates<br />

need to gradually build support around them and generate a general consensus over the<br />

importance and the specific framing of the problem at hand. There is the risk that problems<br />

get blocked re-defined or even hijacked by other actors in the process.<br />

It is important to understand that the two routes are modelled by Princen and Rhinard as two


43<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

ends of a spectrum. In reality it is unlikely that an agenda-setting process follows only one of<br />

them in all stages. Over the whole process of agenda-setting issues and problems may change<br />

from one route into another. Moreover, both processes can unfold simultaneously and have<br />

reciprocal effects on each other.<br />

Microfinance in Europe – problem structures and policy implications<br />

Based on the developed conceptual framework for analyzing agenda-setting processes in the<br />

<strong>European</strong> Union the issue of <strong>microfinance</strong> in Europe can be operationalised to lay the<br />

groundwork for the further analysis of the specific processes of policy initiation in the<br />

<strong>European</strong> Union. The first step in doing this is to identify the general problem structure,<br />

<strong>microfinance</strong> appeals to as a policy tool in Europe. Building on this it should be possible to<br />

assess the social and political implications of <strong>microfinance</strong> in Europe that can be framed into<br />

policy images.<br />

Regarding the problem structure one have to consider that <strong>microfinance</strong> operations in<br />

Europe have a different emphasis as the original approach in underdeveloped countries. The<br />

central problem <strong>microfinance</strong> addresses in Europe is a market failure of credit allocation in<br />

the developed financial markets of Western Europe, mostly due to rising cost and risk<br />

awareness on the side of banks in lending small business loans to start-ups, SMEs and<br />

entrepreneurs without collateral. In Central and Eastern Europe the problem arises due to a<br />

lack of capable financial intermediaries. In this regard, credit can be considered as a semipublic<br />

good, since it is an important factor of production in capitalist economies v . Its<br />

distribution can produce externalities with grave implications for economic and societal<br />

developments in society. Lacking access to business credit for some parts of the population,<br />

due to market failure on the supply side can therefore be seen as a problem that demands<br />

public policy action.<br />

Another aspect of the problem structure <strong>microfinance</strong> appeals to as a policy tool in developed<br />

countries is the change in the <strong>org</strong>anisation of labour towards new forms of self-employment<br />

and the resulting need of adaptations in the interplay between labour market policies, state<br />

investments and welfare state development (Pearson 1998: 812). In this view <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

shares common ground with the rise of ‘market friendly’ social and employment policies<br />

connected to the so called ‘third way’-ideologies in the Mid-Nineties (Schreiner/Morduch<br />

2002: 19-21). Finally <strong>microfinance</strong> can be seen as a tool to tackle the recently recognised<br />

problem of stagnating numbers of enterprise start-ups and restricted access to<br />

entrepreneurship in the <strong>European</strong> economies.<br />

Based on this assessment the social and political implications of <strong>microfinance</strong> can be located<br />

between social, employment and economic policy. A further specification of its attachment to<br />

policy fields depends on the target group approach and the <strong>org</strong>anisational form chosen in the<br />

provision of <strong>microfinance</strong>. In this regard is important to note that <strong>microfinance</strong> providers in<br />

Europe perform their services in very different ways. Some are working at national level<br />

(ADIE [Association pour le droit à l’initiative économique] in France or Finnvera in Finland),<br />

others operate at local level. Some are originally charity <strong>org</strong>anisations (Prince’s Trust in the<br />

UK) others are private <strong>org</strong>anisations aiming at making profit (Fundosz Mikro in Poland).<br />

Providers in Western Europe focus on identified target groups to support mainly business<br />

start ups. In Central and Eastern Europe the microlending providers focus more on existing<br />

SMEs to bridge their financial gaps of running business activities. Regarding the main target<br />

group of <strong>microfinance</strong> providers in Western Europe, Rosalind Copisarow stated in 2004:<br />

“[..] micro-finance in the West has been primarily introduced as a tool to combat the<br />

social and financial exclusion of a segment of society that lies between the poor and<br />

nonpoor: i.e. a population group that falls below the radar screens of commercial<br />

banks but above the upper limits of most forms of charitable/state support”.<br />

(Copisarow 2004: 16)


44<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

The average loan amount given out by <strong>microfinance</strong> providers in Europe was 7700 EUR in<br />

the EU-25 and 10.243 EUR in the EU-15 in 2005 (see Underwood 2006). Additionally, it is<br />

important to recognise that <strong>microfinance</strong> providers in Europe often maintain close contacts<br />

to start-up and business support networks, financial planning support and welfare service<br />

<strong>org</strong>anisations (see Nolan 2003: 81). Most of them offer complex support packages for their<br />

clients, encompassing training and professional support. Policy implications of <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

in Europe are therefore to be seen more in the active support of entrepreneurs and micro<br />

enterprises rather than in the establishing of a new class of financial services. As the<br />

illustration shows, this includes social policy as well as entrepreneurial/economic policy and<br />

labour market/employment policy. Not included here is the policy field of financial<br />

regulation, to which <strong>microfinance</strong> operations are connected if they are provided by nonbanks.<br />

Figure 1: Microfinance and policy fields<br />

Social policy<br />

Target group<br />

socially<br />

excluded<br />

Microfinance<br />

Employment policy<br />

Enterprise/Economic<br />

policy<br />

Target group<br />

SMEs without<br />

access to bank<br />

finance<br />

Since the <strong>microfinance</strong> sectors in Western Europe are yet underdeveloped and in need of<br />

public support to grow, policy measures connected to the issue of <strong>microfinance</strong> are mainly<br />

measures to foster <strong>microfinance</strong> operations. They can be direct or indirect, concerning public<br />

action or regulatory measures. Direct measures like public <strong>microfinance</strong> programmes, public<br />

guarantees and funding for private <strong>microfinance</strong> programmes as well as tax measures to<br />

foster private investment in SMEs (either directly or via fonds, banks or <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

programmes) are widespread. More indirect measures include the direct support of start-ups<br />

in the target groups of <strong>microfinance</strong> programmes through training offers and financial<br />

support for <strong>microfinance</strong> target groups like welfare bridges for start-ups out of<br />

unemployment. Additionally the regulatory framework for giving out credit in the national<br />

financial systems is of strong importance for <strong>microfinance</strong> operations, since some regulations<br />

permit efficient and sustainable <strong>microfinance</strong> operations. Recently, an expert group of DG<br />

Enterprise has identified the most important aspects of such reforms (see COM 2007a). They<br />

include regulations to allow non-banks to give out credit, the cutting of usury caps and the<br />

definition of a set of (minimal) legal standards for <strong>microfinance</strong> <strong>org</strong>anisations.<br />

Summing up, the provision of <strong>microfinance</strong> in Europe can be seen as an innovative financial<br />

tool to foster self-employment and the development of micro enterprises and SMEs. On the


45<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

one hand it challenges established views on the functioning of the financial and economic<br />

system. On the other hand it fits relatively well into recent developments of market conform<br />

social policies and traditions of socially aware banking in Europe. As a policy issue it offers<br />

many options to build policy images that include specific aspects of its provision and exclude<br />

others. From a political science perspective it seems important to analyze which of these<br />

images have been dominant in the process of agenda-setting at the EU level and which actors<br />

where successful in placing and supporting them in specific policy venues.<br />

The policy community of <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

Regarding the policy community that drives the agenda-setting process of <strong>microfinance</strong> in<br />

the <strong>European</strong> Union, two groups of actors should be distinguished, state actors and non-state<br />

actors. State actors that are concerned with the issue of <strong>microfinance</strong> at the <strong>European</strong> level<br />

can be found in national administrations and governments as well as in <strong>European</strong><br />

institutions. Since the <strong>European</strong> Commission is the central actor in the development of policy<br />

initiatives and therefore the formal agenda-setting process of the <strong>European</strong> Union, the<br />

analysis concentrated on members of the different DGs.<br />

Relevant non-state actors are mainly identified in <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> practitioners and<br />

<strong>microfinance</strong> experts that together form a <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> community. The role of<br />

<strong>European</strong> interest groups <strong>org</strong>anisations like the UAPME or <strong>European</strong> banking <strong>org</strong>anisations<br />

was considered in the analysis, but showed no significant influence on the process. Regarding<br />

the <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> community a distinction is drawn between expert networks and<br />

individual policy entrepreneurs. The most important expert network in the process was<br />

identified in the <strong>European</strong> Microfinance Network (EMN) that can be seen as an epistemic<br />

community which members share a vision and have accepted competence in the field of<br />

<strong>microfinance</strong> in Europe vi . Other networks like the Network of <strong>European</strong> Financial<br />

Institutions (NEFI) and the Eastern-Europe Microfinance Centre (MFC) played only a minor<br />

role in the analysed process.<br />

With an online survey the attitudes of the members of the <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

community towards <strong>microfinance</strong> as a <strong>European</strong> policy issues were explored. The survey<br />

covered general aspects of <strong>microfinance</strong> as a <strong>European</strong> policy issue as well as more specific<br />

questions and was sent to 120 persons that have worked on <strong>microfinance</strong> at the <strong>European</strong><br />

level. This encompassed participants of EU working groups on <strong>microfinance</strong>, members of the<br />

EMN and members of the <strong>European</strong> Commission. Beside other aspects, the results indicated<br />

that with Maria Nowak the president of the EMN, the <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> community<br />

features a central figure that acted as policy entrepreneurs throughout the process. Therefore,<br />

an interview with Ms. Maria Nowak was conducted during the EMN conference in Berlin as<br />

well as with Dr. Jan Evers, Co-Founder of the EMN, who was also mentioned as a central<br />

person in the process. Additionally discussions were held with different practitioners and<br />

experts during the EMN/MFC conference in Budapest and the EMN conference in Berlin.<br />

The route of <strong>microfinance</strong> in the <strong>European</strong> Union<br />

The process of policy initiation regarding the issue of <strong>microfinance</strong> in the <strong>European</strong> Union is<br />

not yet concluded. Nevertheless it reached a peak in 2007 with the announcement of the<br />

“<strong>European</strong> initiative on the development of micro-credit” (COM 2007b). Using the<br />

introduced terminology of agenda-setting phases, this can be seen as issue entrance, since<br />

<strong>microfinance</strong> now has entered the formal institutional agenda of the <strong>European</strong> Union. The<br />

next steps in the policy making process will be the beginning of the formation of more<br />

specific EU policy measures on <strong>microfinance</strong>.<br />

Based on the framework of Princen and Rhinard the whole process of agenda-setting building<br />

up to this point can be understood as a agenda-setting route that combines elements of a ‚low


46<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

politics’-route (role of experts, ‚bottom-up’ evolution of the issue in the commission’s<br />

administration) as well as elements of a ‘high politics’ route (role of high-level policy makers<br />

in the <strong>European</strong> Council‚ top-down’ development in EU institutions). The activities that were<br />

identified as milestones in the different phases of the process are chronologically listed in the<br />

following table, including the involved actors and the allocation to the high or low politics<br />

route.<br />

Table 1: Milestones in the agenda-setting process of mirofinance as a <strong>European</strong><br />

policy issue<br />

Year Actors Activity Phase Route<br />

Experts, Interest groups, <strong>European</strong><br />

1998-<br />

Commission (DG Enterprise, DG<br />

2002<br />

Employment)<br />

First studies and scientific projects,<br />

Recomendations of 2nd Round table of<br />

Banks and SMEs<br />

Issue initiation low<br />

Council of the <strong>European</strong> Union Guarantee window for microcredit in the Issue initiation high<br />

2000- (ECOFIN), <strong>European</strong> Council, EIB, Multi-annual Programme for Enterprises<br />

2002 <strong>European</strong> Comission<br />

and Entrepreneurship (MAP) (2000-<br />

2005)<br />

DG Regio<br />

2002<br />

Microcredit as instrument of risk capital<br />

financing (Financial Engineering)<br />

Issue specification high<br />

DG Enterprise<br />

Working group: Microcredit for Small Issue specification low<br />

National administrations<br />

Business and Business Creation: Bridging<br />

2003 Experts<br />

a Market Gap<br />

2003-<br />

2005<br />

DG Employment and Social Affairs<br />

Experts<br />

Setting up of EMN, study on <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

as tool to fight social exclusion<br />

Issue specification low<br />

2003 <strong>European</strong> Council Presidency conclusions with request for<br />

more activity on <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

Issue expansion high<br />

2004 EMN, DG Enterprise 1. Microfinance-<strong>Conference</strong> in Brussels Issue expansion low<br />

2005<br />

<strong>European</strong> Commission, <strong>European</strong><br />

Parliament, Council of the <strong>European</strong><br />

Union<br />

Inclusion of microcredit into the<br />

Integrated Guidelines for growth and<br />

employment (guideline 15)<br />

Issue expansion high<br />

2005-<br />

2006<br />

DG Regio, EIB<br />

JEREMIE (Joint <strong>European</strong> Resources for<br />

Micro to Medium Enterprises)<br />

Issue expansion high<br />

2007 <strong>European</strong> Commission, EMN <strong>European</strong> initiative for the development of<br />

Issue entrance low<br />

micro-credit<br />

Issue initiation<br />

The Commission-funded studies and projects between 1998 and 2002 were the first<br />

systematic work conducted on <strong>microfinance</strong> operations in Europe and acted as reference<br />

points for the further development of <strong>microfinance</strong> as policy issue. They established the most<br />

important aspects of political representation of <strong>microfinance</strong> in Europe that were taken up<br />

later in policy images: <strong>microfinance</strong> as efficient tool to finance SMEs without access to banks<br />

(Evers et al 1999); <strong>microfinance</strong> as tool to fight social exclusion and unemployment (Nowak<br />

et al. 1999); <strong>microfinance</strong> as tool for local development (nef et al 2001) and <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

provision as a challenge to the regulation of the <strong>European</strong> financial systems (Reifner 2002).<br />

In retrospective, the collaborations that were formed to write these studies acted as a nucleus<br />

for an emerging expert community on <strong>microfinance</strong> in Europe that would finally evolve into<br />

the EMN. These activities indicate an issue initiation on the low-politics route, with non-state


47<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

experts and their contact persons in the Commission’s administration as the pivotal actors,<br />

successfully initiating the agenda-setting process of <strong>microfinance</strong> referring to “professional<br />

concerns” (Princen/Rhinard 2006:1122) supported by the provision of data and expertise.<br />

Thus with regard of the role the EU institutions played in this phase of the process, this<br />

notion cannot be maintained. Mostly because the main impulses for the first recognition of<br />

the issue of <strong>microfinance</strong> at EU level came top-down from the systemic level of the <strong>European</strong><br />

Union. Especially the political dynamics of the Lisbon Strategy and the concerns in Council,<br />

Commission and Parliament about instruments to address the financing gap for SMEs in<br />

Europe provided the political momentum for the start of the further agenda-setting process<br />

on <strong>microfinance</strong>. Therefore, the issue initiation of <strong>microfinance</strong> has to be located mainly on<br />

the high politics route. The activities of non-state experts played a supporting role in this<br />

phase of the process. A role that should became more influential in the following<br />

development of the agenda-setting.<br />

Issue specification<br />

A similar mixture of top-down and bottom-up activities was observed during the phase of<br />

issue specification that took place in the years between 2002 and 2005. Yet the influence of<br />

non-state experts, especially from the emerging <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> community, was<br />

stronger and more important than during the initiation phase. Issue specification developed<br />

over three main policy venues: the venues of social/employment policy, enterprise policy and<br />

regional/structural policy. All three venues were mainly governed by the accordant DGs of<br />

the Commission.<br />

The explorative online survey showed that the policy image of <strong>microfinance</strong> as a tool to fight<br />

poverty and social exclusion was closest to the self-conception of most of the representatives<br />

of <strong>microfinance</strong> providers <strong>org</strong>anised in the EMN and was strongly supported by their<br />

representatives during the process of agenda-setting. Additionally the institutional conditions<br />

for the involvement of non-state actors were especially favourable regarding social and<br />

employment policy in the <strong>European</strong> Union, since this venue is generally dominated by the<br />

horizontal aspect of policy making. This DG Employment and Social Affairs mainly acts as<br />

coordinator of trans-national cooperation between stakeholders in the member states to<br />

develop and support innovative policy measures for policy transfer throughout Europe. With<br />

the <strong>European</strong> Employment strategy (EES) and the OMC Social inclusion, this policy venue<br />

offered non-state actors in the past years many opportunities to frame and place policy<br />

images of their policy projects (see de la Porte/Pochet 2005).<br />

The analysis identified multiple references for a direct involvement of the <strong>European</strong><br />

<strong>microfinance</strong> community in the issue specification process on <strong>microfinance</strong> in this policy<br />

venue. The non-state experts were successful in placing a policy image of <strong>microfinance</strong> that<br />

emphasized its use as a tool to fight poverty and social exclusion in Europe as well as to<br />

stimulate employment (see Siewertsen et al 2005). DG Employment and Social Affairs itself<br />

supported the community in this phase substantially with funds for network building and the<br />

awarding of study projects, which in turn were used to further frame the policy image of<br />

<strong>microfinance</strong>.<br />

Similar to the venue of social/employment policy the mode of governance in the policy venue<br />

of enterprise policy is characterized by activities of the DG Enterprise to facilitate<br />

coordination and exchange between the member states and the relevant interest groups (see<br />

Linsenmann et al. 2007). But in contrast to social/employment policy the involvement of<br />

non-state experts in this venue is normally rather limited and focuses on the deliverance of<br />

technical expertise in working groups. This has not much changed with the introduction of<br />

an Open Method of Coordination in 2000 to develop a supportive environment for SMEs and<br />

start-ups in Europe (<strong>European</strong> Council 2000: 5).<br />

The analysis showed that during the phase of issue specification the political representation


48<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

of <strong>microfinance</strong> in this venue changed markedly. It developed from an early policy image<br />

characterized by an emphasis on the support of start-ups with high-growth potential and<br />

already existent small and craft enterprises (COM 2001: 15) into a wider one that explicitly<br />

understands <strong>microfinance</strong> as well as a tool to support socially excluded target groups (COM<br />

2006: 8). As main driver of this change in representation of the issue, the analysis identified<br />

non-state experts and their influence on the outcome of a working group that was installed in<br />

2003 by DG Enterprise. The formation of this working group was mainly a top-down<br />

decision, connected to the need of the Commission to develop a well-founded position on<br />

<strong>microfinance</strong> due to its inclusion into the MAP. But during the consultations the involved<br />

non-state experts were successful in using their technical expertise to change the original<br />

framing of the issue towards a definition that was more in line with the positions of the<br />

<strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> community. The influential report of the group, titled “Microcredit<br />

for Small Business and Business Creation: Bridging a Market Gap” defined <strong>microfinance</strong> in<br />

Europe as the granting of business loans up to 25 000 EUR and, for the first time in this<br />

venue, explicitly included lending to social excluded into the definition (COM 2003: 3). So,<br />

despite institutional conditions that offered them only limited access to the specification<br />

process, non-state actors of the Microfinance community were successful in opening up the<br />

policy image of <strong>microfinance</strong> for the support of excluded target groups and to be compatible<br />

to the policy image developed in the social/employment policy venue.<br />

Unlike the other venues the venue of structural and cohesion policy is characterised by an<br />

interventional mode of governance (Knill 2005: 197), with DG Regio as the main actor, that<br />

develops strategic guidelines for the EU policy on the base of the budget guidelines given by<br />

the Council and in coordination with the national and regional actors responsible for<br />

program implementation (see Allen 2005). DG Regio also cooperates with the EIB/EIF,<br />

which activities are the main instruments of EU structural policy besides the structural funds.<br />

The analysis showed that the issue specification of <strong>microfinance</strong> was closely connected with<br />

the aim to redesign the EU structural funds towards financial engineering and risk capital<br />

financing vii . This aim mainly resulted from the need to adapt the structural policy guidelines<br />

of the <strong>European</strong> Union to the difficult task of developing instruments for regional policy in an<br />

enlarged EU-25 with many underdeveloped regions lacking functioning financial sectors for<br />

enterprise financing. The political representation of <strong>microfinance</strong> in the area of structural<br />

policy was markedly influenced by the experiences of DG Regio and the EIB/EIF with<br />

funding programmes in Eastern Europe and showed until 2005 no hints of closer<br />

coordination with the other DGs working on <strong>microfinance</strong> in Europe. Microcredit was<br />

defined by DG Regio at first as loans with amounts up to 10.000€ (COM 2002: 29), while at<br />

the same time DG Enterprise defined microcredit as loans up to 25.000€ (COM 2003: 3).<br />

The later development of the political representation in this venue shows an adaptation in<br />

terms of definitions, but the policy image of <strong>microfinance</strong> as a tool for financial engineering<br />

kept being dominated by technical aspects (e.g. leverage effects; role of guarantee<br />

intermediaries like the EIF), and the involvement of non-state actors was mostly reduced to<br />

the provision of technical expertise and data (modes of <strong>microfinance</strong> operation, portfolio<br />

structures, market potentials viii ; etc).<br />

The phase of issue specification was characterised by different levels of influence and<br />

involvement of the <strong>European</strong> Microfinance community. Most of these differences can be<br />

explained by institutional conditions that were most favourable in the venue of social and<br />

employment policy. The policy images of <strong>microfinance</strong> that were shaped in this phase started<br />

out quite different in the observed venues, due to diverging interests on the side of the<br />

involved DGs. During the phase the <strong>European</strong> microfiance community successfully opened<br />

up these images for a wider representation of <strong>microfinance</strong> as a policy tool addressing the<br />

financial gap for SMEs as well as social exclusion. Since the policy image of <strong>microfinance</strong> as<br />

instrument for financial engineering was mainly technical defined it also could be attached to<br />

this political representation.


Issue expansion<br />

49<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

In the phase of issue expansion, starting in 2003, aspects of a high politics-route were<br />

dominating again the process of agenda-setting. The mentioning of <strong>microfinance</strong> in the<br />

presidency conclusion of the <strong>European</strong> Council 2003 (<strong>European</strong> Council 2003) gave new<br />

political momentum to the process, spawning activities from DGs that were up to this point<br />

less involved in the process of agenda-setting, like DG Market and DG EcoFin and pushing<br />

already involved DGs into more activity. Another systematic influence on the process was the<br />

reformulation of the Lisbon process in the year 2005. Especially the growing recognition of<br />

entrepreneurship as an enabler for growth and employment in Europe (see COM 2004)<br />

opened up further opportunities for framing <strong>microfinance</strong> as a tool to reach the Lisbon goals<br />

and drew new actors into the process.. The observed strong support by the <strong>European</strong><br />

parliament for an inclusion of <strong>microfinance</strong> into the “Integrated Guidelines for Growth and<br />

Jobs”(COM 2005) emphasizes this. The first Microfinance <strong>Conference</strong> in Brussels on the<br />

other hand can be seen as expansion on the low politics route as it widened the recognition<br />

fort he issue based on sharing technical expertise and the experience of practitioners in the<br />

field.<br />

Issue entrance<br />

The announcement of the Commission in 2006 to develop a <strong>European</strong> action plan on<br />

microcredit, which led to the “<strong>European</strong> initiative for the development of micro-credit” in<br />

2007 (COM 2007), is interpreted here as the entrance of the issue on the formal institutional<br />

agenda of the <strong>European</strong> Union. The specific dynamics that led up to this decision could not<br />

be cleared entirely on the empirical base of the study. Nevertheless some aspects can be<br />

identified, that played a major role in this phase.<br />

In the documents that framed the issue of <strong>microfinance</strong> as an issue that should be addressed<br />

by an action-plan of the Commission (EUROFI 2006, Hübner 2006), the connection of the<br />

political representation of <strong>microfinance</strong> to the socio-economic goals of the Lisbon Strategy is<br />

most striking. Through the agenda-setting process the <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> community<br />

was obviously successful in establishing a policy image of <strong>microfinance</strong> that framed the issue<br />

as „exactly the kind of instrument that we are looking for in Europe to promote growth, jobs<br />

and innovation while reinforcing social cohesion“. (vgl. Hübner 2006:1).<br />

Drawing on the concepts of Kingdon (Kingdon 1996) the development in this final phase of<br />

the agenda-setting process can be seen as the result of a successful strategy of coupling the<br />

already specified issue of <strong>microfinance</strong> with highly visible and recognized problem definitions<br />

available at the systematic level of the EU. The Lisbon Strategy can be understood in this<br />

sense as a temporal window of opportunity for the <strong>European</strong> microcredit community with the<br />

EMN president Maria Nowak as the central policy entrepreneur. Especially between 2005<br />

and 2007, after the relaunch of the Lisbon Strategy, Ms.Nowak constantly campaigned for<br />

the idea of developing the <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> sector as part of strategies for more growth<br />

and employment in Europe. In doing this, mostly in direct contacts to the commission but<br />

also in speeches at high-level EU conferences, she was able to <strong>org</strong>anise a coalition of decisionmakers<br />

inside the Commission to support the development of a <strong>European</strong> action plan on<br />

microcredit. But this success of coupling <strong>microfinance</strong> to the goals of the Lisbon Strategy was<br />

only possible thanks to a ‚softening up’-process (vgl. Kingdon 1995: 127-131), in which<br />

<strong>microfinance</strong> was established as a policy issue in different policy venues of the <strong>European</strong><br />

Commission. The analysis showed that this was mainly possible due to the “collective<br />

entrepreneurship” of the <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong> community <strong>org</strong>anised in the EMN (Zito<br />

2001: 590) and the availability of multiple access points for it, due to the adoption of the<br />

Open Method of Coordination in the fields of social and economic policy. The relevance of<br />

this ‘preparatory work’ for the final step of agenda-setting shows in the speech of


50<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

Commisioner Hübner on the announcement of an action plan on microcredit: ‚[T]here has<br />

already been a great deal of cooperation within the Commission, and there is enormous<br />

interest in the development of micro-finance’ (Hübner 2006: 7).<br />

Following Princen and Rhinard’s framework such a development is part of a low politics<br />

route of agenda-setting, on which the growing engagement with a given issue at lower levels<br />

of policy-making creates a self-sustaining dynamic that leads to “a point of no return” in<br />

expanding the activity toward high level institutions. (vgl Princen/Rhinard 2006: 1122).<br />

Conclusion<br />

The main findings of the research underline the important role of the <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

community, the EMN and its president Ms. Nowak in the process of positioning <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

as a policy issue at EU-level. The analysis also showed that the influence of the <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

experts was highest during the phase of issue specification and that they were successful in<br />

using their technical expertise on the issue of <strong>microfinance</strong> provision to shape the dominant<br />

policy image of <strong>microfinance</strong> at the EU-level to fit their position toward the issue.<br />

Another key result is the finding that the success of <strong>microfinance</strong> as a policy issue at EU-level<br />

was strongly connected to the availability of accessible policy venues, mainly thanks to the<br />

Open Method of Coordination in social and economic policy. The observation that the<br />

specification of <strong>microfinance</strong> as a tool in structural policy was characterised by a stronger<br />

influence of the Commission and member state actors of regional policy, strengthens the<br />

thesis that the institutional conditions of the different policy venues were an important factor<br />

regarding the involvement and influence of the <strong>microfinance</strong> community.<br />

Since the <strong>European</strong> initiative on the development of microcredit” demarks a new step in the<br />

issue career of <strong>microfinance</strong> it will be interesting to see how future changes in the EU modes<br />

of governance will affect accessibility to the EU policy-making for the <strong>European</strong> <strong>microfinance</strong><br />

community. Since decision-making in the <strong>European</strong> Union is characterised rather by the use<br />

of power resources and bargaining than by knowledge and technical expertise, it will become<br />

more difficult to <strong>org</strong>anise the consensus needed to pass policy measures for the development<br />

of <strong>microfinance</strong> in Europe. But the chances for continuous political momentum are good,<br />

since the research showed, that the success of bringing <strong>microfinance</strong> to the institutional<br />

agenda of the EU could be traced back to the fact that the issue of <strong>microfinance</strong> received<br />

support as well form the institutional top as form the base of the <strong>European</strong> Union.<br />

References<br />

Baumgartner, Frank R. and Jones, Bryan D. (1993): Agendas and instability in<br />

American politics: Chicago [et.al.].<br />

Cobb, R.W. und Elder, C.D. (1972): Participation in American Politics: The Dynamics of<br />

Agenda-Building, Baltimore.<br />

Copisarow, Rosalind (2004): Street UK: Lessons learned after its first 3 years'<br />

operations: London.<br />

EUROFI (2006): The development of microcredit in the <strong>European</strong> Union - A tool for<br />

growth and social cohesion - Executive Summary , Paris.<br />

<strong>European</strong> Commission (2001): Commission staff working paper: Enterprises' access to<br />

finance, SEC (2001) 1667, Brussels.<br />

<strong>European</strong> Commission (2002): Guide to Risk Capital Financing in Regional Policy,<br />

Brussels.<br />

<strong>European</strong> Commission (2003): Microcredit for Small Business and Business Creation:<br />

Bridging a Market Gap, Brussels.


51<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

<strong>European</strong> Commission (2005) Integrated guidelines for growth and jobs (2005-2008),<br />

COM (2005) 141 final, Brussels.<br />

<strong>European</strong> Commission (2006): Communication from the Commission to the Council,<br />

the <strong>European</strong> Parliament, the <strong>European</strong> Economic and Social Committee and the Committee<br />

of the Regions: Umsetzung des Lissabon-Programms der Gemeinschaft: Implementing the<br />

Community Lisbon Programme: Financing SME Growth – Adding <strong>European</strong> Value, COM<br />

(2006) 349 final, Brussels.<br />

<strong>European</strong> Commission (2007a): The Regulation of Microcredit in Europe: Expert Group<br />

Report, Brussels.<br />

<strong>European</strong> Commission (2007b): Communication from the Commission to the Council,<br />

the <strong>European</strong> Parliament, the <strong>European</strong> Economic and Social Committee and the Committee<br />

of the Regions: A <strong>European</strong> initiative for the development of micro-credit in support of<br />

growth and employment<br />

<strong>European</strong> Council (2000): Presidency conclusion, 23. und 24. März, Lisbon.<br />

Evers, Jan; Jack, Stefanie; Loeff, Adriaan and Siewertsen, Hedwig (1999):<br />

Reducing Cost and Managing Risk in Lending to Micro Enterprises: Handbook for Micro-<br />

Lending in Europe, Zeist/Hamburg.<br />

Evers, Jan; Lahn, Stefanie and Jung, Martin (2007): Status of Microfinance in<br />

Western Europe - an academic review: EMN issue paper, Paris.<br />

Forster, Sarah; Greene, Seth und Pytkowska, Justyna (2003): The state of<br />

<strong>microfinance</strong>: in Central and Eastern Europe and the new independent states, Washington<br />

D.C..<br />

Haas, Peter M. (1992): Introduction: epistemic communities and international policy coordination,<br />

in: International Organization, 46, pp.1-35.<br />

Hübner, Danuta (2006): Micro-Credit A Strategy for Europe: Speech held at the EUROFI<br />

<strong>Conference</strong>:''Retail Financial Services in Europe'', 7 th of June 2006, Brussels.<br />

Kingdon, John W. (1995): Agendas, alternatives, and public policies, 2. Ed., New York.<br />

Knill, Christoph (2005): Die Politiken der EU, in: Katharina Holzinger et.al (Ed.): Die<br />

Europäische Union: Theorein und Analysekonzepte, Paderborn, pp. 181-214.<br />

La Porte, Caroline de and Pochet, Philippe (2005): Participation in the Open Method<br />

of Co-ordination. The Cases of Employment and Social Inclusion, in: Jonathan Zeitlin und<br />

Philippe Pochet (Ed.): The Open Method of Co-ordination in Action - the <strong>European</strong><br />

Employment and Social Inclusion Strategies, Brussels, pp. 353-390.<br />

Linsenmann, Ingo; Meyer, Christoph O. and Wessels, Wolfgang (2007):<br />

Economic government of the EU: a balance sheet of new modes of policy coordination:<br />

Basingstoke, Hampshire [et.al.].<br />

Mintrom, Michael (1997): Policy Entrepreneurs and the Diffusion of Innovation, in:<br />

American Journal of Political Science, 41(3), pp.738-771.<br />

nef; Evers & Jung; Fondazione Choros; INAISE (2001): Finance for local<br />

development: New solutions for public-private action, London.<br />

Nolan, Alistair (2003): Entrepreneurship and Local Economic Development, in: Mark<br />

Drabenstott; Nancy Novack und Bridget Abraham (Ed.): Main Streets of Tomorrow:<br />

Growing and Financing Rural Entrepreneurs, Kansas City, pp. 77-90.<br />

Nowak, Maria; Mezieres, Eric; Evers, Jan et al. (1999): Integration of the socially<br />

excluded through self-employment and microcredit in Europe, Paris.<br />

Parrish, Richard (2003): Sports law and policy in the <strong>European</strong> Union, Manchester.<br />

Peters, B. Guy (2006): Agenda-Setting in the <strong>European</strong> Union, in: Jeremy Richardson<br />

(Hrsg.): <strong>European</strong> Union: power and policy-making, London, pp. 78-94.<br />

Princen, Sebastiaan and Rhinard, Mark (2006): Crashing and creeping: agendasetting<br />

dynamics in the <strong>European</strong> Union, in: Journal of <strong>European</strong> Public Policy, 13(7),<br />

pp.1119-1132.<br />

Princen, Sebastiaan (2007): Agenda-setting in the <strong>European</strong> Union, in: Journal of<br />

<strong>European</strong> Public Policy, 14(1), pp.21-38.<br />

Radaelli, Claudio M. (1995): The role of knowledge in the policy process, in: Journal of


52<br />

5 th <strong>Annual</strong> <strong>Conference</strong> <strong>Nice</strong><br />

<strong>European</strong> Public Policy, 2(2), pp.159-183.<br />

Reifner, Udo (2002): Microlending - a case for regulation in Europe, Baden-Baden.<br />

Richardson, Jeremy (2006): Policy-making in the EU, in: Jeremy Richardson (Ed.):<br />

<strong>European</strong> Union: power and policy-making London [et.al.]. pp. 3-26.<br />

Ripley, Randall B. (1985): Policy analysis in political science, Chicago.<br />

Schreiner, Mark and Morduch, Jonathan (2002): Opportunities and Challanges for<br />

Microfinance in the United States, in: James H. Carr und Zhong Yi Tong (Ed.): Replicating<br />

Microfinance in the United States, Washington DC. pp. 19-61.<br />

Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1912): Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, Wien.<br />

Siewertsen, Hedwig et al. (2005): Policy measures to promote the use of micro-credit<br />

for social inclusion; Study conducted on behalf of the <strong>European</strong> Commission DG<br />

Employment, Social Affairs and Equal Opportunities, unit E/2, Zeist.<br />

Underwood, Tamara (2006): Overview of the Microcredit Sector in Europe 2004-2005,<br />

Paris.<br />

Whiley, Claire; Kempson, Elaine und Evers, Jan (2000): Banks and Micro-lending,<br />

Hamburg.<br />

Notes<br />

1 MFI D’s outreach worker is here included as a manager. The timesheet data of this staff<br />

group is only included in the analysis of the use of time of the <strong>org</strong>anisation as a whole.<br />

ii Following Knill, different administrational cultures manifest themselves mainly in different<br />

modes of involving interest groups into the process of policy-making and in divergent norms<br />

and interests (Knill 2005: 206)<br />

iii Mintrom defines policy entrepreneurs as a class of political actors that can significantly<br />

increase the probability of consideration and adoption of policy innovations through their<br />

presence and actions (Mintrom 1997).<br />

iv A Cross-cutting issue is understood here as an issue that encompasses different policy<br />

fields, e.g. environment protection or gender equality.<br />

v The important role of credit for the economical development was already emphasized by<br />

Schumpeter (see Schumpeter 1912).<br />

vi The results of the exploratory online survey supported such a view. Members of the EMN<br />

showed similar patterns in their attitudes towards <strong>microfinance</strong> as a policy issue. However,<br />

the number of participants was too low to produce representative results.<br />

vii A development that is in turn closely connected to a growing distribution of policies to<br />

foster SMEs as a central element of local and regional development strategies in Europe<br />

(Nolan 2003: 79).<br />

viii E.g. : In preparation of the JEREMIE-initiative, the MFC produced a study for the EIF on<br />

the market potential for <strong>microfinance</strong> in Poland

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!