04.09.2013 Views

Modelling the accruals process and assessing unexpected accruals*

Modelling the accruals process and assessing unexpected accruals*

Modelling the accruals process and assessing unexpected accruals*

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Modelling</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> <strong>process</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>assessing</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong>*<br />

Cheng Y. Lai**<br />

Australian School of Business, University of New South Wales, NSW 2052 Australia.<br />

This Version: Feb 2010<br />

Abstract<br />

This paper has two objectives. First, it formalizes <strong>the</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> <strong>process</strong> for both normal <strong>and</strong><br />

abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> under clean surplus accounting in order to better underst<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir drivers. My<br />

analysis reveals that <strong>the</strong> factors that drive normal <strong>accruals</strong> are growth in income <strong>and</strong> changes in<br />

accrual <strong>and</strong> deferral policies, while abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> are driven by growth in income <strong>and</strong> a<br />

change in accounting policies. Second, this paper assesses <strong>the</strong> bias in <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> (<strong>the</strong><br />

empirical measure) from existing <strong>accruals</strong> models in capturing abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> (<strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>oretical<br />

construct), <strong>and</strong> provides determinants <strong>and</strong> a reason for <strong>the</strong> bias. For well-specified accrual<br />

models, <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> are biased by two factors – income distortion in <strong>the</strong><br />

benchmark firms involved in <strong>the</strong> estimation procedure <strong>and</strong> deviation in operating policies<br />

between <strong>the</strong> firm in question <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms. A plausible explanation for this bias lies<br />

in <strong>the</strong> inherent correlation between normal <strong>and</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>. If accrual models are ill-<br />

specified, <strong>the</strong> omission of relevant variables is likely to fur<strong>the</strong>r bias <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong>.<br />

Keywords: Accruals; Accruals <strong>process</strong>; Abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>; Normal <strong>accruals</strong>; Expected<br />

<strong>accruals</strong>; Unexpected <strong>accruals</strong>; Earnings management; Accruals management<br />

JEL classification: G12, M41<br />

*This paper forms part of my PhD dissertation.<br />

** Email: cheng.lai@unsw.edu.au. Tel: +61-2-9385-6609. Fax: +61-2-9385-5925<br />

1


1 Introduction<br />

The focus of earnings management research to date has been on <strong>the</strong> identification, motivation,<br />

<strong>and</strong> consequences of earnings management (Healy <strong>and</strong> Wahlen 1999). This paper attempts to<br />

address <strong>the</strong> identification issue while remaining silent about <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r two issues. One common<br />

approach to identifying earnings management is via <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> where total <strong>accruals</strong> are<br />

regressed on variables that are proxies for normal <strong>accruals</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> are <strong>the</strong><br />

unexplained components or residual of total <strong>accruals</strong> (see Healy <strong>and</strong> Wahlen 1999 for details).<br />

The common <strong>accruals</strong> models employed in <strong>the</strong> literature are <strong>the</strong> Jones model (Jones 1991) <strong>and</strong><br />

subsequent modifications, notably <strong>the</strong> modified Jones model found in Dechow et al. (1995) <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> model in Ball <strong>and</strong> Shivakumar (2006) that incorporates conditional conservatism.<br />

However, all of <strong>the</strong>se models were developed on an ad-hoc basis <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>the</strong>oretical validity is<br />

open to question. McNicols (2000) argues that this black-box approach reduces confidence in <strong>the</strong><br />

ability of estimates of abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> capture <strong>the</strong> exercise of accounting discretion by<br />

management. The paper addresses this concern by focussing on two main objectives. First, this<br />

paper defines <strong>accruals</strong>, explores <strong>the</strong> role of normal <strong>and</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>, <strong>and</strong> models <strong>the</strong>m in a<br />

general setting. This helps us to better underst<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> drivers of normal <strong>and</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> so<br />

that researchers can adopt a systematic approach (ra<strong>the</strong>r than a black-box approach) in<br />

identifying <strong>the</strong> factors that explain <strong>accruals</strong>. Second, I assess <strong>the</strong> bias in <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> (<strong>the</strong><br />

empirical measure) from <strong>the</strong> aforementioned <strong>accruals</strong> models in capturing abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> (<strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong>oretical construct) <strong>and</strong> provide determinants <strong>and</strong> a reason for <strong>the</strong> bias. To my knowledge, this<br />

is <strong>the</strong> first paper that has done this to date. This contribution is significant in that it provides new<br />

2


insights into what <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> actually capture, what determines <strong>the</strong> direction <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

magnitude of <strong>the</strong>ir bias or contamination, <strong>and</strong> why such a bias or contamination arises.<br />

I begin by adopting <strong>the</strong> idea in Richardson et al. (2005) to comprehensively measure <strong>accruals</strong> by<br />

subtracting <strong>the</strong> income under cash accounting from <strong>the</strong> income under accrual accounting. In<br />

addition to <strong>the</strong> balance sheet approach provided in Richardson et al. (2005), I also consider <strong>the</strong><br />

income statement approach to calculate <strong>accruals</strong> under clean surplus accounting. This<br />

reconciliation offers insight into <strong>the</strong> conclusion in Hribar <strong>and</strong> Colins (2002) that <strong>the</strong> <strong>accruals</strong><br />

calculated under both methods are different.<br />

With this <strong>accruals</strong> definition in mind, I first model normal <strong>accruals</strong> as <strong>the</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> resulting from<br />

<strong>the</strong> neutral accrual <strong>process</strong> that shifts cash flow recognition in income to a time that unbiasedly<br />

reflects underlying fundamentals. As <strong>the</strong> sum of accrued <strong>and</strong> deferred components, normal<br />

<strong>accruals</strong> are driven by growth in income <strong>and</strong> changes in <strong>accruals</strong> <strong>and</strong> deferrals policies. Second, I<br />

model abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> as <strong>the</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> that distort <strong>the</strong> neutral <strong>accruals</strong> <strong>process</strong> by accelerating<br />

<strong>and</strong>/or delaying cash flow recognition in income. The two factors that drive abnormal <strong>accruals</strong><br />

are a change in accounting policy <strong>and</strong> forward income growth. Finally, I combine <strong>the</strong> normal <strong>and</strong><br />

abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> into <strong>the</strong> final <strong>accruals</strong> model under clean surplus accounting.<br />

My model is appealing in that it does not impose restrictive assumptions on firms‟ fundamentals.<br />

It merely requires (a) <strong>the</strong> basic accounting identity to hold, (b) <strong>accruals</strong> to alter <strong>the</strong> timing of cash<br />

flow recognition in income over time, <strong>and</strong> (c) <strong>the</strong> aggregated income to be equal to <strong>the</strong><br />

aggregated cash flow over <strong>the</strong> life span of firms. These three conditions can hardly be regarded<br />

3


as assumptions as <strong>the</strong>y simply depict how accounting works. This is in contrast to Dechow,<br />

Kothari, <strong>and</strong> Watts (1998), who model <strong>the</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> <strong>process</strong> based on assumptions about accounts<br />

receivable, accounts payable, sales, purchases, <strong>and</strong> inventory. 1<br />

More importantly, I decompose <strong>accruals</strong> into normal <strong>and</strong> abnormal components <strong>and</strong> model <strong>the</strong>m<br />

separately, while <strong>the</strong>ir model is silent on <strong>the</strong> effect of accounting distortions. This approach is<br />

crucial to <strong>the</strong> second objective of this paper for two reasons. First, it enables me to assess <strong>the</strong> bias<br />

in <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> in capturing abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> determinants of this bias. Second,<br />

<strong>the</strong> separate modeling of normal <strong>and</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> allows me to explore <strong>the</strong> correlation<br />

between <strong>the</strong> two. This contrasts with previous studies which simply assume that <strong>the</strong> two<br />

components are independent of each o<strong>the</strong>r (such as Jones 1991 <strong>and</strong> Dechow et al. 1995). It turns<br />

out that this correlation is a crucial factor in explaining why <strong>the</strong> bias in <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong><br />

arises in <strong>the</strong> first place.<br />

Based on this <strong>the</strong>oretically derived <strong>accruals</strong> model, I develop an <strong>accruals</strong> model (referred to as<br />

<strong>the</strong> „encompassing model‟ from here on) that uses variables in <strong>the</strong> Jones model. This model is<br />

shown to be <strong>the</strong>oretically equivalent to <strong>the</strong> model in Dechow <strong>and</strong> Dichev (2002) after adjusting<br />

for <strong>the</strong> drivers of depreciation expense, <strong>and</strong> to also encompass <strong>the</strong> Jones model, <strong>the</strong> modified<br />

Jones model, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Ball-Shivakumar model. I subsequently investigate whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong><br />

component of <strong>the</strong>se five models are biased or contaminated in capturing <strong>the</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong><br />

1 First, accounts receivable is assumed to be a constant proportion of sales that follow a r<strong>and</strong>om walk <strong>process</strong>.<br />

Second, <strong>the</strong>y assume an inventory adjustment <strong>process</strong> in which inventory at a period consists of a target level <strong>and</strong> a<br />

deviation from that target, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> target inventory is a constant fraction of next period‟s forecasted cost of sales.<br />

Finally, accounts payable is assumed to be a constant proportion of purchases, which in turn is a function of <strong>the</strong><br />

sales generating <strong>process</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> inventory adjusting <strong>process</strong>.<br />

4


attributed to <strong>the</strong> firm‟s biased accounting policy <strong>and</strong> provide <strong>the</strong> determinants of such<br />

contamination.<br />

For well-specified models like <strong>the</strong> encompassing model <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> modified version of <strong>the</strong> Dechow<br />

<strong>and</strong> Dichev (2002) model, my analysis reveals that <strong>the</strong>ir resulting <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> capture<br />

deviations in accounting <strong>and</strong> operating policies between <strong>the</strong> firm in question <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> set of<br />

applicable benchmark firms (benchmark firms are ei<strong>the</strong>r cross-sectionally comparable firms or<br />

<strong>the</strong> firm‟s own specific time-series history). Hence, <strong>the</strong> resulting measure of <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong><br />

is biased or contaminated by two factors – income distortion by <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms <strong>and</strong><br />

deviation in operating policy between <strong>the</strong> firm in question <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms. Depending<br />

on <strong>the</strong> relative magnitudes of <strong>the</strong>se two factors, <strong>the</strong> resulting <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will be<br />

exacerbated or attenuated relative to abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>. Only when <strong>the</strong>se two factors are absent<br />

will <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> from well-specified models fully capture abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>; o<strong>the</strong>rwise,<br />

<strong>the</strong> resulting measure of <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will be contaminated.<br />

It may seem puzzling prima facie as to why measures of <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> estimated from<br />

well-specified models are contaminated. I show that a plausible explanation for this is that <strong>the</strong>re<br />

is an inherent correlation between abnormal <strong>and</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong>, <strong>and</strong> this correlation is zero<br />

only when <strong>the</strong> two factors are absent. (Let us illustrate this correlation with a conservative firm<br />

that recognizes revenue when its cash flow is realized ra<strong>the</strong>r than when it is earned. The<br />

recognition of credit revenue will initiate positive normal accounts receivables in <strong>the</strong> period<br />

when <strong>the</strong> revenue is earned. For this conservative firm to fully delay this recognition so that no<br />

receivables are recognized, it needs to initiate an equal amount of negative abnormal accounts<br />

5


eceivables to offset <strong>the</strong> positive normal accounts receivables. As normal receivables increase,<br />

more negative abnormal receivables are needed to offset this increase.) This inherent correlation<br />

violates <strong>the</strong> zero conditional assumption imposed by ordinary least squares (OLS) that <strong>the</strong><br />

expected component is orthogonal to <strong>the</strong> disturbance term. As a result, <strong>the</strong> regression approach to<br />

extract abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> as <strong>the</strong> disturbance term is likely to be problematic.<br />

If <strong>accruals</strong> models are ill-specified, <strong>the</strong> omitted relevant variables will be captured by <strong>the</strong><br />

disturbance term; <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>y are likely to fur<strong>the</strong>r contaminate <strong>the</strong> resulting <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong>.<br />

This is especially <strong>the</strong> case for <strong>the</strong> Jones model, which omits lagged revenue <strong>and</strong> next period‟s<br />

change in revenue from its explanatory variables that are intended to capture normal <strong>accruals</strong>. In<br />

addition to normal changes in underlying performance (as discovered in Dechow et al 1995), my<br />

paper shows that two o<strong>the</strong>r factors (or determinants) are likely to contaminate Jones-type<br />

measures of <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong>. These are normal changes in accrual policy <strong>and</strong> normal<br />

deferred <strong>accruals</strong>. The modified-Jones model suffers from similar problems to <strong>the</strong> Jones model.<br />

Finally, since conditional conservatism is an accounting distortion, its incorporation into <strong>the</strong><br />

Ball-Shivakumar model tends to fur<strong>the</strong>r contaminate <strong>the</strong> measure of <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> by<br />

attributing abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> from conditional conservatism as expected <strong>accruals</strong>.<br />

The remainder of <strong>the</strong> paper continues as follows. Section 2 defines <strong>accruals</strong> <strong>and</strong> reconciles direct<br />

<strong>and</strong> indirect methods to calculate <strong>accruals</strong>. Section 3 explores <strong>the</strong> accrual <strong>process</strong> <strong>and</strong> models<br />

normal <strong>and</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>. Section 4 assesses determinants of <strong>the</strong> bias in <strong>unexpected</strong> in<br />

capturing abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>. Section 5 demonstrates <strong>the</strong> correlation between normal <strong>and</strong><br />

abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>, while section 6 concludes.<br />

6


2 Direct <strong>and</strong> indirect method to calculate <strong>accruals</strong><br />

2.1 Accounting identity<br />

To calculate comprehensive <strong>accruals</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir decomposition, I first specify <strong>the</strong> stock <strong>and</strong> flows<br />

clean-surplus relations (or accounting identity) for total working capital assets, non-current<br />

operating assets, <strong>and</strong> financial liabilities. I start by modifying <strong>the</strong> basic accounting identity<br />

Asset t =Liability t +Equity t to reflect operating <strong>and</strong> financing activities as (<strong>the</strong> firm j subscript is<br />

omitted from <strong>the</strong> modeling <strong>process</strong> in this paper till section 4)<br />

CASH NOA NFO CSE<br />

t t t<br />

t (1)<br />

where CASH t is cash on h<strong>and</strong>, NOA is non-cash net operating assets that consists of total<br />

working capital assets (TWC) which arise from day-to-day operating activities <strong>and</strong> non-current<br />

operating assets (NCO) which arise as a result of capital expenditures, NFO is non-cash net<br />

financial obligations or liabilities, <strong>and</strong> CSE is common shareholders equity.<br />

The clean surplus relations or identities of <strong>the</strong>se items are summarized in Table 1. These<br />

specifications are similar to those in Feltham <strong>and</strong> Ohlson (1995) <strong>and</strong> Penman (2009), who<br />

separate firms‟ activities into operating <strong>and</strong> financing. However, this paper fur<strong>the</strong>r separates<br />

operating activities into short-term operating activities that affect day-to-day working capital <strong>and</strong><br />

long-term operating activities that affect capital investment decisions.<br />

[Table 1 about here]<br />

7


CASH identity: C is cash flow from operations, I is cash flow to investments in operations, (C–I)<br />

is widely known as <strong>the</strong> free cash flow, F represents <strong>the</strong> cash outflow for non-equity financing<br />

activities, <strong>and</strong> D is cash outflow from equity-financing activities (it will be negative if <strong>the</strong>re is a<br />

net contribution from shareholders). This identity asserts that changes in cash on h<strong>and</strong> are<br />

attributable to free cash flow plus (debt <strong>and</strong> equity) financing cash flow. It will be reduced to <strong>the</strong><br />

cash conservation equation in Penman (2009) if <strong>the</strong>re is no change in cash on h<strong>and</strong>.<br />

TWC identity: OIB is comprehensive operating income before depreciation <strong>and</strong> amortization.<br />

TWC includes accounts receivable, inventory, accounts payable, deferred <strong>and</strong> accrued<br />

components of <strong>accruals</strong> of o<strong>the</strong>r revenue <strong>and</strong> expenses that stem from day-to-day operations <strong>and</strong><br />

are due within <strong>and</strong> beyond twelve months. This relation asserts that total working capital is<br />

increased by <strong>the</strong> amounts earned in OIB <strong>and</strong> reduced by net operating cash flow (C).<br />

NCO identity: DA is depreciation <strong>and</strong> amortization expenses, which also include realized or<br />

unrealized losses or gains in non-current operating assets. 2 NCO includes both (depreciable <strong>and</strong><br />

non-depreciable) tangible <strong>and</strong> intangible assets that stem from investments on operations. It is<br />

increased by <strong>the</strong> purchase of new assets net of cash receipt from assets disposal (I) <strong>and</strong> it is<br />

reduced by depreciation <strong>and</strong> assets‟ disposal net of asset revaluation (DA).<br />

NOA identity: OI is comprehensive operating income. This identity is simply a combination of<br />

TWC <strong>and</strong> NCO identities. It asserts that <strong>the</strong> change in NOA is increased by what is earned in OI<br />

<strong>and</strong> what is purchased as assets during <strong>the</strong> period (I). However, <strong>the</strong>y are reduced by <strong>the</strong> cash<br />

2 Realised or unrealised gains or losses in <strong>the</strong>se assets can be regarded as <strong>the</strong> reversal or <strong>the</strong> result of initial<br />

measurement error in depreciation <strong>and</strong> amortisation expenses.<br />

8


flow associated with income recognised in <strong>the</strong> past, current or future periods (C). 3 In short, NOA<br />

is increased by OI <strong>and</strong> reduced by free cash flow.<br />

NFO identity: NFE is comprehensive financing expense (net of financing income). NFO includes<br />

loans, income tax liabilities, preference shares, investments on marketable securities, <strong>and</strong><br />

minority interests. It is increased by financing expenses incurred but reduced by actual payment<br />

of financing expenses <strong>and</strong> principal repayments.<br />

CSE identity: CNI is comprehensive income. This identity can also be obtained if one combines<br />

cash, NOA, <strong>and</strong> NFO identities. It asserts that owner‟s equity in a firm is increased by income<br />

<strong>and</strong> reduced by net distributions to shareholders.<br />

2.2 Accrual calculation <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> reconciliation between indirect <strong>and</strong> direct methods<br />

The key difference between accrual <strong>and</strong> cash basis accounting lies in <strong>the</strong>ir timing of recognition<br />

(Statement of Financial Accounting Concepts, No. 6 Paragraph 144). Cash accounting<br />

recognizes a transaction when <strong>the</strong> associated cash flow is realized ra<strong>the</strong>r than expected. As a<br />

result, <strong>the</strong> change in net operating assets in <strong>the</strong> NOA identity <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> change in net financial<br />

t<br />

obligation in NFO identity Table 1 are both zero under cash accounting (i.e., NOA 0<strong>and</strong> t<br />

NFO 0 ), where <strong>the</strong> subscript c denotes cash accounting. 4 This associated with <strong>the</strong> basic<br />

c<br />

3 According to Dechow <strong>and</strong> Dichev (2002), Ct consists of<br />

t<br />

t 1 t<br />

t 1<br />

, C , <strong>and</strong><br />

t<br />

C t<br />

t<br />

t<br />

. C offsets <strong>the</strong> cash transactions<br />

t<br />

t 1<br />

recognized in OI. C t 1<br />

reduces NOA <br />

t 1<br />

when earnings recognized in <strong>the</strong> past are received. C , cash flows received<br />

for earnings to be recognized in future periods, will create operating liability that reduces NOA.<br />

4 This is because C=OIB, I = DA, <strong>and</strong> F=NFE under cash accounting.<br />

C <br />

t<br />

c<br />

9


accounting identity in expression (1) implies that <strong>the</strong> change in common equity is simply equal<br />

to <strong>the</strong> change in cash under cash accounting.<br />

Like Richardson et al. (2005), I measure <strong>accruals</strong> as <strong>the</strong> difference between comprehensive<br />

income under accrual accounting <strong>and</strong> comprehensive income under cash accounting as follows:<br />

TACC CNICNI t t t<br />

c<br />

t t t<br />

OIB Ct DA It FE Ft<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

TWC NCO NFO<br />

t t t<br />

Given <strong>the</strong> articulation of income statement to balance sheet, equation (2) demonstrates that <strong>the</strong><br />

same total <strong>accruals</strong> can be calculated indirectly from <strong>the</strong> balance sheet variables or directly from<br />

<strong>the</strong> cash flow <strong>and</strong> income variables. This is signified by <strong>the</strong> last two lines in equation (2) which<br />

stem from <strong>the</strong> TWC, NCO, <strong>and</strong> NFO identities in Table 1. 5<br />

First, total working capital <strong>accruals</strong> can be indirectly calculated as <strong>the</strong> change in total working<br />

capital assets or indirectly calculated as comprehensive operating income before depreciation<br />

<strong>and</strong> amortisation expense minus operating cash flow. Second, non-current operating <strong>accruals</strong> can<br />

be indirectly calculated as <strong>the</strong> change in non-current net operating assets, or directly calculated<br />

as capital expenditures minus comprehensive depreciation <strong>and</strong> amortisation expenses. Third,<br />

operating <strong>accruals</strong> (<strong>the</strong> sum of <strong>the</strong> previous two <strong>accruals</strong>) can be indirectly calculated as <strong>the</strong><br />

change in non-cash net operating assets, or directly calculated as comprehensive operating<br />

income minus free cash flow. Finally, financing <strong>accruals</strong> can be indirectly calculated as <strong>the</strong><br />

5 However, data availability could favour one method over ano<strong>the</strong>r. For instance, it will be easier to calculate<br />

<strong>accruals</strong> from cash flows for U.S. data as long term receivables <strong>and</strong> investments in marketable securities are grouped<br />

into one item #32 in Compustat.<br />

(2)<br />

10


change in net financial obligations, or directly calculated as net financing expenses minus non-<br />

equity financing cash flow.<br />

The reason why direct <strong>and</strong> indirect methods may result in different measures (in Hribar <strong>and</strong><br />

Collins 2002) is because <strong>the</strong> income used to calculate <strong>accruals</strong> under <strong>the</strong> direct method is not<br />

comprehensive. Dirty surplus items are by definition items that increase net assets <strong>and</strong> bypass <strong>the</strong><br />

income statements (Penman 2004). If <strong>the</strong>se items have been accounted for in <strong>the</strong> calculation of<br />

<strong>accruals</strong>, <strong>the</strong> direct <strong>and</strong> indirect methods will yield <strong>the</strong> same measure of <strong>accruals</strong>. For instance,<br />

had <strong>the</strong> impact of foreign currency translations been accounted for, a classic dirty surplus item, it<br />

would not lead to different measures of <strong>accruals</strong> under direct <strong>and</strong> indirect methods.<br />

The compliance of <strong>the</strong> clean surplus relation is not an assumption, but ra<strong>the</strong>r is simply a<br />

depiction of how accounting works. All clean surplus relations in section 2.1 reflect <strong>the</strong> basic<br />

accounting identity of Asset = Liability + Equity. A violation of <strong>the</strong> clean surplus accounting<br />

implies a violation of this basic accounting identity <strong>and</strong> a violation of <strong>the</strong> fundamental<br />

accounting premise that debits equal credits. For accounting to work, <strong>the</strong> clean surplus relation or<br />

identity, by definition, has to hold. The empirical evidence that is not in favor of clean surplus<br />

relation does not automatically reject its existence. It can simply be due to <strong>the</strong> lack of data items<br />

to comprehensively calculate <strong>the</strong> dirty surplus or non-articulation items. In short, <strong>accruals</strong> under<br />

<strong>the</strong> direct <strong>and</strong> indirect methods should be <strong>the</strong> same if appropriate adjustments are made to ei<strong>the</strong>r<br />

method in compliance with clean surplus relations or accounting identities.<br />

11


3 The accrual <strong>process</strong> in detail<br />

3.1 The role of <strong>accruals</strong><br />

Accruals are <strong>the</strong> temporary adjustment between income <strong>and</strong> cash flow during a period. Income is<br />

<strong>the</strong> by-product of accrual accounting that records <strong>the</strong> financial effect of an entity as it occurs<br />

ra<strong>the</strong>r than when <strong>the</strong> cash flow is realized (Statement of Financial Accounting Concepts, No. 6<br />

Paragraph 139). It is defined in Statement of Financial Accounting Concepts, No.1 Paragraph 45<br />

(<strong>and</strong> similarly in Statement of Financial Accounting Concepts, No. 5 Paragraphs 36 <strong>and</strong> 38) as<br />

performance measures that relate <strong>the</strong> benefits from <strong>and</strong> to <strong>the</strong> costs of operations <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

transactions, events, <strong>and</strong> circumstances that affect an enterprise during a period. 6<br />

Essentially, income matches <strong>the</strong> obligations against <strong>the</strong> claims of cash flow during a period while<br />

cash flow matches realized cash outlays against actual cash receipts. However, <strong>the</strong> realization of<br />

cash flow <strong>and</strong> claims to <strong>and</strong> obligations of cash flow (i.e., income) need not occur in <strong>the</strong> same<br />

period. Specifically, <strong>the</strong> income recognized in a particular period t is attributable to <strong>the</strong> cash flow<br />

realized at, before, <strong>and</strong> after this period, while <strong>the</strong> cash flow realized in <strong>the</strong> same period are<br />

attributable to <strong>the</strong> income recognized at, before, <strong>and</strong> after this period. Accruals, as <strong>the</strong> difference<br />

between <strong>the</strong> two, are equal to<br />

6 According to SFAC 5-36, income is a measure of performance during a period that is concerned primarily with <strong>the</strong><br />

extent to which asset inflows, associated with substantially completed cash-to-cash cycles, exceed asset outflows,<br />

associated directly or indirectly with <strong>the</strong> same cycles. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, SFAC 5-38 says that income focuses on what <strong>the</strong><br />

entity has received or reasonably expects to receive for its output (revenues) <strong>and</strong> what it sacrifices to produce <strong>and</strong><br />

distribute that output (expenses). Income also includes results of <strong>the</strong> entity‟s incidental or peripheral transactions <strong>and</strong><br />

some effects of o<strong>the</strong>r events <strong>and</strong> circumstances stemming from <strong>the</strong> environment (gains <strong>and</strong> losses).<br />

12


t t<br />

TACC CNICFt T<br />

t t t titti CNI tiCNItCNItiCFtCFtCFt <br />

<br />

i1<br />

T<br />

t t titi CNI tiCNItiCFtCFt <br />

<br />

i1<br />

where CNI is <strong>the</strong> comprehensive net income, CF is <strong>the</strong> cash flow from non-equity sources (i.e.,<br />

CFt = ∆CASHt+Dt), <strong>and</strong> T represents <strong>the</strong> number of periods it takes <strong>accruals</strong> to reverse. The<br />

subscript denotes <strong>the</strong> period where cash flow is realized <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> superscript denotes <strong>the</strong> period<br />

where income is recognized. This identity is first highlighted in Dechow <strong>and</strong> Dichev (2002). 7<br />

The two components of <strong>accruals</strong> are <strong>the</strong> accrued component <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> deferred component, in<br />

which <strong>the</strong>ir cash flow realization respectively supersedes <strong>and</strong> precedes <strong>the</strong> associated income<br />

recognition. While <strong>the</strong> former includes outst<strong>and</strong>ing expenses <strong>and</strong> accrued revenue, <strong>the</strong> latter<br />

includes revenue received in advance, expenses paid in advance, <strong>and</strong> depreciation <strong>and</strong><br />

amortization expenses. Since <strong>accruals</strong> are temporary adjustments, <strong>the</strong> initiation of an accrual<br />

item will be reversed in <strong>the</strong> latter periods. In particular, <strong>the</strong> accrued component of <strong>accruals</strong> is<br />

initiated when it is recognized in income <strong>and</strong> reversed when its associated cash flow is realized.<br />

Alternatively, <strong>the</strong> deferred component of <strong>accruals</strong> is initiated when <strong>the</strong> cash flow is realized <strong>and</strong><br />

reversed when <strong>the</strong>y are recognized in income.<br />

The initiated accrued component ( CNI ) <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> reversed deferred component ( CNI ) are<br />

t<br />

t i<br />

embedded in recognized income. They are <strong>the</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> that shift cash flow realized before <strong>and</strong><br />

after period t to income recognition in period t. Alternatively, <strong>the</strong> reversed accrued component<br />

7 t t<br />

Income recognised <strong>and</strong> realised in period t equals cash flow realised <strong>and</strong> recognised in period t, i.e. CNIt CFt<br />

(3)<br />

t<br />

t i<br />

.<br />

13


( CF ) <strong>and</strong> initiated deferred component ( CF ) are embedded in realized cash flow. They are<br />

t i<br />

t<br />

t i<br />

t<br />

<strong>accruals</strong> that shift cash flow realized in period t out of income recognition in period t. In o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

t t<br />

words, <strong>accruals</strong> include both non-cash-related components in income ( CNI CNI ) <strong>and</strong> non-<br />

titi titi income-related components in cash ( CF CF ); <strong>and</strong> this is summarized in Table 2.<br />

t t<br />

[Table 2 about here]<br />

On one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>the</strong> recognition of cash receipts (<strong>and</strong> payments) realized prior to <strong>and</strong> subsequent to<br />

<strong>the</strong> supplies (<strong>and</strong> consumption) of goods <strong>and</strong> services in period t is shifted to income in period t.<br />

On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>the</strong> cash receipts (<strong>and</strong> payments) realized in period t for goods <strong>and</strong> services<br />

supplied (<strong>and</strong> consumed) prior to <strong>and</strong> subsequent to period t are shifted out of income in period t.<br />

This reinforces that <strong>the</strong> main role of <strong>accruals</strong> is to adjust cash flow to obtain income by shifting<br />

cash flow recognition in income between periods (Statement of Financial Accounting Concept,<br />

No. 1, Paragraph 44, Dechow 1994, <strong>and</strong> Dechow <strong>and</strong> Dichev 2002).<br />

3.2 <strong>Modelling</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong><br />

Normal <strong>accruals</strong> are <strong>the</strong> resulting <strong>accruals</strong> from <strong>the</strong> neutral <strong>accruals</strong> <strong>process</strong> that shifts cash flow<br />

recognition (in <strong>and</strong> out of income) to <strong>the</strong> time at which it unbiasedly reflects firms‟ underlying<br />

fundamentals, i.e., <strong>the</strong>y are <strong>the</strong> „perfect foresight‟ <strong>accruals</strong>. The role of <strong>accruals</strong> in shifting cash<br />

flow recognition in income implies that income during a period is made up of cash flows realized<br />

in different periods. Essentially, <strong>the</strong> cash flow realized in period t <strong>and</strong> recognized in period t+i<br />

(t–i) is <strong>the</strong> same as <strong>the</strong> income realized in period t <strong>and</strong> recognized in period t+i (t–i). Once <strong>the</strong><br />

14


period of income recognition <strong>and</strong> cash realization is specified, income <strong>and</strong> cash flow can be<br />

written interchangeably in expression (3).<br />

If CF is replaced with CNI <strong>and</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> are assumed to reverse in one period (i.e., T=1) 8 , <strong>the</strong>n<br />

expression (3) becomes<br />

<br />

t1 t1t t <br />

u, t u, t u, t u, t 1 u, t 1<br />

TACC CNI CNI CNI CNI<br />

(4)<br />

where <strong>the</strong> superscript (subscript) denotes <strong>the</strong> period of income recognition (cash realization) <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> u superscript represents <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong>se accrual items are „unbiased‟ <strong>and</strong> reflect <strong>the</strong><br />

„underlying‟ economic reality. One can rearrange expression (4) as follows<br />

where<br />

<br />

11 TACC a CNI CNI a a CNI<br />

u, t t u, t u, t1 t t1 u, t1<br />

t1 t1 t<br />

t u, t1 u, t t1 t u, t1<br />

dtCNICNIdtdtCNI <br />

a CNI CNI<br />

t u, t u, t<br />

t1 t1<br />

a CNI CNI<br />

t1 u, t1 u, t1<br />

t t<br />

d CNI CNI<br />

t u, t u, t<br />

t1 t1<br />

d CNI CNI<br />

t1 u, t1 u, t1<br />

t t<br />

The actual or underlying proportion of <strong>the</strong> accrued component initiated (reversed) in income is<br />

t t 1<br />

measured by at 1 ( at ). Likewise,<br />

t 1<br />

d t<br />

t<br />

( t 1<br />

(5)<br />

15<br />

d ) measures <strong>the</strong> underlying proportion of <strong>the</strong><br />

deferred component initiated (reversed) in income. These parameters are positive when <strong>the</strong><br />

associated revenue is larger than <strong>the</strong> expenses <strong>and</strong> vice versa. Since <strong>accruals</strong> reversal takes place<br />

within one period, <strong>the</strong> reversed parameter<br />

t 1<br />

at t<br />

( t 1<br />

t t 1<br />

initiated parameters at 1 ( d t<br />

) of <strong>the</strong> previous period.<br />

d ) of <strong>the</strong> current period will be <strong>the</strong> same as <strong>the</strong><br />

8 This model can be generalized to <strong>the</strong> case where <strong>accruals</strong> take more than 1 period to reverse. See Appendix 1.


If cash flow recognition in income is accelerated <strong>and</strong>/or delayed, <strong>the</strong> resulting proportions will<br />

change from <strong>the</strong>ir underlying proportions. For instance, if more accrued income (i.e., <strong>the</strong><br />

difference between accrued revenue <strong>and</strong> accrued expenses) is initiated than <strong>the</strong> underlying<br />

accrued income, <strong>the</strong> proportion of <strong>the</strong> initiated accrued component embedded in income will be<br />

t<br />

different from <strong>the</strong> underlying proportion (if at 1 is not equal to one). Hence, <strong>the</strong>se four<br />

parameters can be seen as indirectly capturing <strong>the</strong> timing-recognition of accrued <strong>and</strong> deferred<br />

components.<br />

Expression (5) indicates that normal <strong>accruals</strong> consist of accrued (in <strong>the</strong> first line) <strong>and</strong> deferred<br />

components (in <strong>the</strong> second line). In particular, <strong>the</strong> accrued component is shown to be a function<br />

of growth in income <strong>and</strong> changes in accrual policy. It will be higher if <strong>the</strong>re is more growth in<br />

income, holding <strong>the</strong> accrual policy constant. Even if <strong>the</strong>re is no growth in income, firms can end<br />

up with more accrued component of <strong>accruals</strong> if <strong>the</strong>re is a change in accrual policy to grant more<br />

credit sales to debtors or to decrease <strong>the</strong> proportion of outst<strong>and</strong>ing expenses. 9 If income <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

accrual policy are both constant, <strong>the</strong> accrued component of <strong>accruals</strong> will be zero as <strong>the</strong> reversed<br />

<strong>and</strong> initiated components will offset one ano<strong>the</strong>r.<br />

In contrast, <strong>the</strong> deferred component of <strong>accruals</strong> is driven by forward income growth <strong>and</strong> changes<br />

in <strong>the</strong> deferral policy. Holding deferral policy constant, higher forward income growth will lead<br />

to a higher deferred component of <strong>accruals</strong>. When income growth is zero, firms can end up with<br />

more deferred component of <strong>accruals</strong> if <strong>the</strong>re is a change in deferral policy to pre-pay more<br />

9 Provided that <strong>the</strong> parameter a is positive, i.e. accrued revenue is greater than accrued expenses.<br />

16


expenses or receive less revenue in advance. 10 If <strong>the</strong>re is no growth in underlying income <strong>and</strong> no<br />

change in deferral policy, <strong>the</strong> deferred component will be zero, as its reversed component will<br />

offset <strong>the</strong> initiated component. In short, normal <strong>accruals</strong>, as <strong>the</strong> sum of accrued <strong>and</strong> deferred<br />

components, are driven by growth in income <strong>and</strong> changes in accrual <strong>and</strong> deferral policies.<br />

3.3 <strong>Modelling</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong><br />

3.3.1 Definition of abnormal <strong>accruals</strong><br />

Abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> are <strong>the</strong> reported <strong>accruals</strong> that deviate from underlying <strong>accruals</strong> or <strong>accruals</strong><br />

under a neutral accounting policy. They are <strong>accruals</strong> that distort <strong>the</strong> neutral accrual <strong>process</strong>, <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong>y can be attributed to both intentional <strong>and</strong>/or unintentional measurement errors. Intentional<br />

measurement errors are also referred to as managerial discretion (i.e., managers use <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

discretion to intentionally impose errors in <strong>the</strong>ir accrual estimates by adopting certain accounting<br />

choices.) Since <strong>the</strong> intention of management is unobservable (Dechow <strong>and</strong> Dichev 2002), any<br />

attempts to separate intentional <strong>and</strong> unintentional measurement errors are likely to be superficial.<br />

As a result, this paper treats all measurement errors as undesirable <strong>and</strong> attributes <strong>the</strong>m to<br />

earnings management. 11<br />

While some argue that earnings can also be managed through real activities (Roychowdhury<br />

2006), this paper assumes that <strong>the</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> attributed to real activities management do not<br />

constitute earnings management as long as <strong>the</strong>y represent underlying fundamentals. Healy <strong>and</strong><br />

Whalen (1999) define earnings management as follows:<br />

10 Provided that <strong>the</strong> parameter d is negative, i.e. deferred revenue is less than deferred expenses.<br />

11 While intentional <strong>and</strong> unintentional measurement errors have different contracting implications, <strong>the</strong> separation of<br />

<strong>the</strong> two is irrelevant when it comes to modeling <strong>the</strong> behavior of abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>, see Lai (2009). Also, whe<strong>the</strong>r<br />

intentional measurement errors or managerial discretion are efficient or opportunistic (see Watts <strong>and</strong> Zimmerman<br />

1986) is not <strong>the</strong> focus of this paper which merely focuses on <strong>the</strong> identification of earnings management.<br />

17


“Earnings management occurs when managers use judgment in financial reporting <strong>and</strong> in<br />

structuring transactions to alter financial reports to ei<strong>the</strong>r mislead some stakeholders about <strong>the</strong><br />

underlying economic performance of <strong>the</strong> company, or to influence contractual outcomes that<br />

depend on reported accounting numbers”<br />

One of <strong>the</strong> keywords in <strong>the</strong>ir definition of earnings management is “alter financial reports to<br />

mislead stakeholders”. Real activities or real earnings management involves <strong>the</strong> management of<br />

real activities <strong>and</strong> it clearly does not alter financial reports. Second, Statement of Financial<br />

Accounting Concepts No. 1 indicates that one of <strong>the</strong> main objectives of financial reporting is to<br />

provide information about enterprise resources, claims to those resources, <strong>and</strong> changes in <strong>the</strong>m.<br />

If <strong>the</strong>re are changes in real activities, financial reports <strong>and</strong> accounting figures are supposed to<br />

reflect <strong>the</strong>se changes. Hence, it is <strong>the</strong> role of financial reporting to reflect firms‟ underlying<br />

fundamentals. The choice of transactions that determine such fundamentals is ano<strong>the</strong>r issue<br />

entirely.<br />

3.3.2 <strong>Modelling</strong> earnings management<br />

Since <strong>accruals</strong> are temporary adjustments, <strong>the</strong> initiation of an accrual item (normal <strong>and</strong> abnormal)<br />

must be reversed at some stage. This implies that aggregated <strong>accruals</strong> over a firm‟s life-span (LP)<br />

are zero <strong>and</strong><br />

LP LP<br />

ti CNI CASH tiDti (6)<br />

i0 i0<br />

Aggregated accrued income is <strong>the</strong> same as aggregated cash income, which is in turn equal to<br />

cash flow from non-equity sources ( titi 18<br />

CASH D ). This relation is consistent with Statement<br />

of Financial Accounting Concepts, No. 1, paragraph 46 <strong>and</strong> it applies to income reported with


any accounting distortions (conservative, aggressive, or neutral). If CNI u is <strong>the</strong> underlying<br />

comprehensive income, <strong>the</strong>n it is also true that<br />

LP LP<br />

tiu, ti CNI CNI<br />

(7)<br />

i0 i0<br />

While fundamentally identical firms can report different periodic income due to accounting<br />

distortions, <strong>the</strong>y should have <strong>the</strong> same aggregate income over <strong>the</strong>ir life-span. Hence, with <strong>the</strong><br />

given fundamentals, <strong>the</strong> only way a firm can artificially inflate (deflate) reported income in <strong>the</strong><br />

current period is to borrow from (lend to) underlying income in future periods. Earnings<br />

management can be simply regarded as a practice that shifts <strong>the</strong> recognition of underlying<br />

income between periods.<br />

If <strong>the</strong> income of a firm is shifted between adjacent periods (i.e., <strong>accruals</strong> reverse in one period) 12 ,<br />

<strong>the</strong>n it can be represented as<br />

1 <br />

CNI CNI m m CNI<br />

(8)<br />

t u, t u, t1<br />

t1, t t, t1<br />

where m t1, t2<br />

is a parameter that represents <strong>the</strong> proportion of underlying income in period t2<br />

embedded in or shifted to underlying income in period t1. The first <strong>and</strong> second subscripts denote<br />

<strong>the</strong> period in which <strong>the</strong> income is recognized <strong>and</strong> from which <strong>the</strong> income is borrowed,<br />

respectively. Zero, negative, <strong>and</strong> positive mtt , 1 signifies neutral, conservative, <strong>and</strong> aggressive<br />

accounting distortions in period t respectively. The first line of equation (8) asserts that <strong>the</strong><br />

reported income during a period is equal to underlying income minus <strong>the</strong> current income lent to<br />

<strong>the</strong> past (i.e., <strong>the</strong> reversal of past abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>) plus <strong>the</strong> income borrowed from <strong>the</strong> future<br />

12 This model can be generalised to <strong>the</strong> case where <strong>accruals</strong> take more than 1 period to reverse. See Appendix 2.<br />

19


(i.e., <strong>the</strong> initiation of abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>). The difference between reported <strong>and</strong> underlying<br />

t u, t<br />

income ( CNI CNI ) is abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> if <strong>the</strong>re is no distortion in reported cash flow.<br />

The main implication from <strong>the</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> model is that abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> are driven by<br />

a change in accounting policy <strong>and</strong> forward income growth. Reported income will be distorted<br />

upward when income growth is positive <strong>and</strong> when <strong>the</strong>re is accounting aggression <strong>and</strong>/or an<br />

increase in <strong>the</strong> aggression level. Similarly, <strong>the</strong>re will be a negative distortion in reported income<br />

when income growth is positive <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>re is conservatism <strong>and</strong>/or an increase in <strong>the</strong> conservatism<br />

level. If one restricts <strong>the</strong> proportion of future underlying income shifted to <strong>the</strong> current period to<br />

be <strong>the</strong> same as <strong>the</strong> proportion of current underlying income shifted to <strong>the</strong> past (i.e., mt1, t mt,<br />

t1),<br />

<strong>the</strong> distortion in reported income is totally driven by <strong>the</strong> growth in income. Under such a<br />

restriction where <strong>the</strong> level of accounting distortions are constant or permanent, <strong>the</strong> model yields<br />

<strong>the</strong> well documented effect that firms tend to understate income when permanent conservatism is<br />

associated with positive growth, with <strong>the</strong> opposite being true for permanent aggression. 13<br />

3.4 Combining normal <strong>and</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> models<br />

Total <strong>accruals</strong> consist of abnormal <strong>and</strong> normal components as follows<br />

t t<br />

TACC CNICFt u, t u, t t u, t u, t<br />

CNI CF CNI CNI CFt CF <br />

<br />

<br />

The items in <strong>the</strong> round brackets are <strong>the</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong> while <strong>the</strong> items in <strong>the</strong> square brackets are<br />

<strong>the</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>. Abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> are simply <strong>the</strong> difference between reported <strong>and</strong><br />

underlying income if <strong>the</strong>re is no distortion in total reported cash flow (as is assumed throughout<br />

13 See Penman (2004) for instance; <strong>and</strong> for more detailed <strong>and</strong> comprehensive analyses on <strong>the</strong> impacts of accounting<br />

distortions on performance measures, please refer to Lai (2009).<br />

(9)<br />

20


this paper). Combining <strong>the</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong> model with <strong>the</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> model (by<br />

substituting expressions (5) <strong>and</strong> (8) into expression (9)), one yields <strong>the</strong> following <strong>accruals</strong> model:<br />

11 <br />

t1tt1 1, , 1 1,<br />

<br />

TACC a CNI CNI a a CNI<br />

t t u, t u, t1 t t1 u, t1<br />

t t t<br />

t u, t1 u, t t1 t u, t1<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

d CNI CNI d d CNI<br />

<br />

m CNI CNI m m CNI<br />

u, t1 u, t u, t1<br />

t t t t t t<br />

As shown in section 2.2, <strong>the</strong>re are different categories of total <strong>accruals</strong>. This <strong>accruals</strong> model can<br />

be generalized to different categories of <strong>accruals</strong> with <strong>the</strong>ir respective clean-surplus flow<br />

components <strong>and</strong> parameters (see Appendix 1 <strong>and</strong> 2 for derivation). Table 3 summarizes <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>accruals</strong> model for total <strong>accruals</strong>, total working capital <strong>accruals</strong>, non-current operating <strong>accruals</strong>,<br />

operating <strong>accruals</strong>, financing <strong>accruals</strong>, <strong>and</strong> short-term <strong>accruals</strong> used in <strong>the</strong> Jones model.<br />

[Table 3 about here]<br />

The different <strong>accruals</strong> models in table 3 look very similar to <strong>the</strong> one in (10) with several<br />

t<br />

exceptions. Firstly, <strong>the</strong>re is an operating cash flow bias in total working-capital <strong>accruals</strong> ( TWC )<br />

t<br />

<strong>and</strong> an associated investing cash flow bias in non-current operating <strong>accruals</strong> ( NCO ). This is to<br />

reflect <strong>the</strong> mis-classification of expenses as assets or revenue as liabilities; or vice versa (see<br />

McVay 2006). For instance, firms that aggressively capitalize research <strong>and</strong> development<br />

expenses will place <strong>the</strong> cash outflows as I ra<strong>the</strong>r than C; this leads to inflated C that is associated<br />

with lower I for <strong>the</strong> same period. There is no such cash flow bias in total <strong>accruals</strong> in (10) because<br />

<strong>the</strong> biases in C <strong>and</strong> I exactly offset one ano<strong>the</strong>r. Secondly, <strong>the</strong>re is no accrual component of<br />

t<br />

<strong>accruals</strong> in non-current operating <strong>accruals</strong> ( NCO ). This is because <strong>the</strong> income statement item<br />

in<br />

t<br />

NCO , depreciation expenses, is similar to deferred components of <strong>accruals</strong> where<br />

(10)<br />

21


ecognition supersedes cash realization (assets are depreciated after <strong>the</strong>y are acquired). Finally,<br />

one obtains <strong>the</strong> short-term <strong>accruals</strong> (<br />

22<br />

t t<br />

WC DA ) by excluding non-current working capital<br />

<strong>accruals</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> cash component of non-current operating <strong>accruals</strong> from ∆NOA. 14 This is <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>accruals</strong> model that I will use in <strong>the</strong> following section in <strong>assessing</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> measures,<br />

given <strong>the</strong> literature commonly uses short-term <strong>accruals</strong> to measure <strong>accruals</strong> (for instance Jones<br />

1991, Hribar <strong>and</strong> Collins 2002).<br />

The <strong>accruals</strong> models in (10) <strong>and</strong> table 3 are developed merely based on <strong>the</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> <strong>process</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> earnings management <strong>process</strong> under clean surplus accounting. They are silent on <strong>the</strong><br />

distortion or bias imposed by accounting st<strong>and</strong>ards, <strong>the</strong> motivation or consequences of earnings<br />

management, <strong>the</strong> signaling role of managers, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> fundamentals of firms. 15 While <strong>the</strong><br />

omission of <strong>the</strong>se factors can be considered as a shortcoming of my model, it also makes my<br />

model applicable in <strong>the</strong> general setting. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, this omission is appropriate given <strong>the</strong><br />

empirical <strong>accruals</strong> models used to identify earnings management are also silent on such issues.<br />

One can certainly incorporate <strong>the</strong>se factors into this model to make a richer <strong>and</strong> sharper inference.<br />

However, this is not <strong>the</strong> objective of this paper which is to assess whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong><br />

<strong>accruals</strong> extracted from empirical <strong>accruals</strong> models are able to fully capture abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> (as<br />

will be seen in <strong>the</strong> next section).<br />

14<br />

In o<strong>the</strong>r words, it is a special case of ∆NOA where (a) I is excluded from non-current operating <strong>accruals</strong> (i.e.<br />

t t<br />

NCO DA ) 14 t<br />

<strong>and</strong> (b) working capital <strong>accruals</strong> take one period to reverse (i.e., T=1 in TWC ), so that only<br />

current operating <strong>accruals</strong> are included.<br />

15<br />

The ever-changing nature of accounting st<strong>and</strong>ards makes it difficult to determine any bias imposed. Given <strong>the</strong><br />

FASB‟s recent favouring of „neutrality‟ over „conservatism‟ (Statement of Financial Accounting Concept, No. 2),<br />

bias resulting from accounting st<strong>and</strong>ards might approximate zero in <strong>the</strong> future.


4 Assessing <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> measures<br />

The identification of earnings management with <strong>the</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> approach critically<br />

depends on <strong>the</strong> ability of <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> to capture abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>. With <strong>unexpected</strong><br />

<strong>accruals</strong> being <strong>the</strong> empirical estimates of abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>, <strong>the</strong> bias in <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> (i.e.,<br />

<strong>the</strong> difference between <strong>the</strong> two) can be determined by three components – measurement error in<br />

variables, heterogeneity in parameters, <strong>and</strong> omitted variables. Measurement error in variables<br />

arises when accurate measures of accounting variables cannot be obtained. Heterogeneity in<br />

parameters arises when parameters of individual observations differ from <strong>the</strong> regression<br />

parameters, which reflect <strong>the</strong> average effect of <strong>the</strong> parameters of <strong>the</strong> observations involved in <strong>the</strong><br />

regression. Finally, <strong>the</strong> omission of relevant variables can also cause a difference between<br />

abnormal <strong>and</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> because <strong>the</strong>y will be captured by <strong>the</strong> regression disturbance<br />

term. Since measurement errors are unavoidable in accounting variables, I only comment on<br />

<strong>the</strong>m whenever appropriate. Much of my analysis will focus on <strong>the</strong> problems of heterogeneity<br />

<strong>and</strong> omitted variables.<br />

4.1 Encompassing model<br />

To derive a more general model that encompasses <strong>the</strong> Jones model, I divide <strong>the</strong> OIB of short-<br />

term <strong>accruals</strong> in table 3 by revenue of <strong>the</strong> same period <strong>and</strong> divide DA by <strong>the</strong> lagged non-current<br />

operating assets. Re-arranging yields<br />

WC DA REV REV REV<br />

t t u, t1 u, t u, t1<br />

j j 0, t 1, t j 2, t j 3, t j<br />

where <strong>the</strong> parameters are represented as<br />

<br />

u<br />

C C ,<br />

NCO NCO <br />

u, t1 u, t<br />

4, t j 5, t j t, j<br />

<br />

t<br />

a<br />

t<br />

da<br />

u, t1<br />

PM<br />

0, t t t<br />

<br />

1, t TWC TWC<br />

(11)<br />

23


<strong>and</strong><br />

where<br />

t a t<br />

d<br />

t<br />

m<br />

u, t PM<br />

t m t<br />

dm t d t<br />

dd<br />

u, t1<br />

<br />

PM<br />

1 t<br />

m u, t<br />

t m t<br />

dm<br />

t<br />

gm u, t1<br />

,<br />

<br />

2, t TWC TWC TWC<br />

<br />

3, t TWC TWC TWC TWC<br />

,<br />

4, t NCO<br />

<br />

5, t NCO NCO NCO<br />

u, t1 REV u, t REV<br />

3, , 3, 4, , 4, 5, , 5,<br />

<br />

<br />

t, j 0, t, j 0, t 1, t, j 1, t j 2, t, j 2, t j<br />

REV NCO NCO<br />

u, t 1 u, t 1 u, t<br />

t j t j t j t j t j t j<br />

ut ,<br />

ut ,<br />

PM represents <strong>the</strong> underlying pre-depreciation profit margin, represents <strong>the</strong><br />

economic depreciation rate, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> j subscript represents individual observation. The parameters<br />

without <strong>the</strong> j subscript ( 0,t to 5,t ) are <strong>the</strong> regression parameters, while <strong>the</strong> parameters with <strong>the</strong> j<br />

subscript ( 0, t, j to 5, t, j<br />

(12)<br />

) are <strong>the</strong> parameters of <strong>the</strong> individual observation. If this model is<br />

estimated using time-series observations of <strong>the</strong> same firm, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> estimated parameters will<br />

reflect <strong>the</strong> time-series averaged parameters. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r h<strong>and</strong>, if this model is estimated using<br />

cross-sectional observations for a given year, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> estimated parameters will reflect <strong>the</strong> cross-<br />

sectional averaged parameters. 16 The implications of my analysis apply to both types of models,<br />

<strong>and</strong> I will refer to both of <strong>the</strong>se time-series observations <strong>and</strong> cross-sectional observations as<br />

„benchmark firms‟.<br />

The encompassing model‟s disturbance term in expression (12) for a particular firm, firm j, is<br />

often referred to as <strong>the</strong> firm j‟s <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong>. It is entirely attributed to <strong>the</strong> heterogeneity<br />

in <strong>the</strong> parameters (i.e., <strong>the</strong> deviation of firm j parameters from parameters of benchmark firms).<br />

This heterogeneity is shown to be due to deviations in accounting <strong>and</strong> operating policies between<br />

16 The <strong>accruals</strong> model in Jones (1991) is originally applied in a time-series fashion. However, <strong>the</strong> cross-sectional<br />

estimation <strong>accruals</strong> model seems to be common (in Kothari, Leone, Wasley 2004 for instance). This is probably due<br />

to <strong>the</strong> superiority of <strong>the</strong> cross-section model over <strong>the</strong> time-series model (see Bartov, Gui, <strong>and</strong> Tsui 2000).<br />

24


firm j <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms. These accounting policies include accounting for working<br />

capital <strong>accruals</strong> ( m <strong>and</strong> dm ) <strong>and</strong> accounting for depreciation expense ( m ,<br />

t<br />

NCO<br />

t<br />

TWC<br />

t<br />

TWC<br />

gm ). Alternatively, <strong>the</strong>se operating policies include accrual policy ( a <strong>and</strong><br />

ut , 1<br />

policy ( d <strong>and</strong> dd ), <strong>and</strong> policies that drive profit margin ( PM ,<br />

t<br />

TWC<br />

t<br />

TWC<br />

ut ,<br />

ut , 1<br />

economic depreciation rate ( <strong>and</strong> ).<br />

t<br />

TWC<br />

t<br />

NCO<br />

t<br />

dmNCO<br />

25<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

t<br />

da TWC ), deferral<br />

ut ,<br />

PM , <strong>and</strong><br />

ut , 1<br />

PM ),<br />

Since <strong>the</strong> heterogeneity in <strong>the</strong> parameters of <strong>the</strong> encompassing model is due to both <strong>the</strong> normal<br />

<strong>accruals</strong> parameters <strong>and</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> parameters, one can express <strong>the</strong> disturbance term as<br />

AbACC AbACC NACC NACC<br />

<br />

(13)<br />

t, j j j<br />

where NACC ( AbACC j<br />

) represents <strong>the</strong> normal (abnormal) <strong>accruals</strong> based on observation<br />

j<br />

specific parameters <strong>and</strong> NACC ( AbACC ) represents <strong>the</strong> normal (abnormal) <strong>accruals</strong> based on<br />

<strong>the</strong> regression parameters. For <strong>the</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> to fully capture abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> (i.e.,<br />

AbACC ), <strong>the</strong>re are two conditions which <strong>the</strong> encompassing model has to satisfy. The<br />

t, j j<br />

first condition is that <strong>the</strong> income of <strong>the</strong> benchmark firm is neutral (i.e., AbACC 0 ) <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

second condition is that <strong>the</strong>re is no deviation in operating policies between firm j <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

benchmark firms (i.e. NACC NACC 0 ). O<strong>the</strong>rwise, <strong>the</strong> firm j‟s <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong><br />

j<br />

<br />

extracted from <strong>the</strong> encompassing model will be biased by one or both of <strong>the</strong>se two factors as<br />

shown in Table 4. 17<br />

17 If one holds <strong>the</strong> view that earnings management includes real activities or real earnings management<br />

(Roychowdhury 2006), <strong>the</strong> deviation in underlying operating policies can be seen as capturing real activities<br />

management. Moreover, my analysis shows that one cannot really disentangle <strong>the</strong> effect of earnings management via<br />

<strong>accruals</strong> <strong>and</strong> earnings management via real activities because <strong>the</strong>y are both captured by <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> in <strong>the</strong><br />

encompassing model. However, as argued in section 3.3.1, this paper holds <strong>the</strong> view that real activities management


[Table 4 about here]<br />

If <strong>the</strong>re is no deviation in operating policies <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms are on average neutral (cell<br />

5 of Table 4), <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will fully capture <strong>the</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>. The encompassing<br />

model appears to be powerful in detecting earnings management. Specifically, <strong>the</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong><br />

<strong>accruals</strong> from this model will be zero for firms not engaging in earnings management. They will<br />

be positive for firms engaging in aggressive earnings management <strong>and</strong> negative for firms<br />

engaging in conservative earnings management. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> magnitude of <strong>the</strong>se <strong>unexpected</strong><br />

<strong>accruals</strong> will be equivalent to abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>.<br />

If <strong>the</strong>re is no distortion in <strong>the</strong> income of <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms but <strong>the</strong>re is a deviation in operating<br />

policies between firm j <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms (in <strong>the</strong> third column of Table 4), <strong>the</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong><br />

<strong>accruals</strong> will be contaminated by <strong>the</strong> amount of this deviation. In particular, <strong>the</strong> firm j‟s<br />

<strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will capture <strong>the</strong> amount of earnings management net of <strong>the</strong> effect from <strong>the</strong><br />

deviation in operating policies. (This deviation can be ei<strong>the</strong>r between this firm <strong>and</strong> its past<br />

history or between this firm <strong>and</strong> its cross-sectional peers.) If this deviation is negative (as in cell<br />

2 of Table 4), <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will be biased downward. Alternatively, <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong><br />

will be biased upward if this deviation is positive (in cell 8 of Table 4). Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong><br />

magnitude of <strong>the</strong>se downward or upward biases in <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will be determined by <strong>the</strong><br />

magnitude of <strong>the</strong> deviation in operating policies ( NACC NACC<br />

j<br />

).<br />

does not constitute earnings management. As a result, <strong>the</strong> deviation in fundamentals is viewed as a contamination of<br />

<strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> that is supposed to capture abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> from non-neutral accounting policy in this paper.<br />

26


If <strong>the</strong>re is no deviation in operating policies but <strong>the</strong> income of <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms is non-<br />

neutral (as in <strong>the</strong> third row of Table 4), <strong>the</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will be contaminated by <strong>the</strong><br />

amount of this distortion. In particular, firm j‟s <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> capture <strong>the</strong> deviation in firm<br />

j‟s accounting policy from <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms, ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> full amount of abnormal <strong>accruals</strong><br />

attributed to <strong>the</strong> firm‟s accounting policy. The classification of firm j as aggressive or<br />

conservative is not relative to an o<strong>the</strong>rwise unbiased accounting policy but it is relative to its<br />

benchmark firms (which can be its own time-series history or cross-sectional peers). If <strong>the</strong><br />

income distortion of <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms is negative (i.e., <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms are conservative),<br />

<strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will be biased upward relative to abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> (as in cell 6). Likewise,<br />

<strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will be biased downward when <strong>the</strong> income distortion of <strong>the</strong> benchmark<br />

firms is positive (as in cell 3). Moreover, <strong>the</strong> magnitude of <strong>the</strong>se upward or downward biases will<br />

equal <strong>the</strong> amount of <strong>the</strong> income distortion of <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms ( AbACC ).<br />

Finally, if <strong>the</strong>re is a deviation in operating policies for firm j <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> income of benchmark firms<br />

is distorted, <strong>the</strong> bias in firm j‟s <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will be a function of <strong>the</strong>se two factors. A<br />

positive distortion in <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms‟ income associated with a negative deviation in<br />

operating policies between firm j <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms will unambiguously bias <strong>unexpected</strong><br />

<strong>accruals</strong> downward (as in <strong>the</strong> case of cell 1 in Table 4). Likewise, a negative distortion in <strong>the</strong><br />

benchmark firms‟ income associated with a positive deviation in operating policies will bias<br />

<strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> upward (as in <strong>the</strong> case of cell 9 in Table 4). The magnitudes of <strong>the</strong>se biases<br />

in firm j’s <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will be equal to <strong>the</strong> amount of <strong>the</strong> income distortion of <strong>the</strong><br />

benchmark firms plus <strong>the</strong> amount of <strong>the</strong> deviation in firm j‟s operating policies.<br />

27


However, <strong>the</strong>re are scenarios in which <strong>the</strong> direction of <strong>the</strong> bias in <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> is<br />

uncertain. This is because <strong>the</strong> deviation in operating policies <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> income distortion of<br />

benchmark firms induces biases in <strong>the</strong> opposite direction <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> net effect depends on <strong>the</strong><br />

relative magnitudes of <strong>the</strong> two biases. This occurs when <strong>the</strong>re is a positive distortion in<br />

benchmark firms‟ income <strong>and</strong> a positive deviation in operating policies (as in <strong>the</strong> case of cell 7)<br />

or when <strong>the</strong>re is a negative distortion in benchmark firms‟ income <strong>and</strong> a negative deviation in<br />

operating policies (as in <strong>the</strong> case of cell 3).<br />

In short, <strong>the</strong> determinants of <strong>the</strong> bias in firm j‟s <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> are attributable to <strong>the</strong><br />

deviation of firm j‟s operating policies from <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> income distortion of<br />

benchmark firms. Whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will be exacerbated, attenuated, or unaffected<br />

relative to abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> will depend on <strong>the</strong> net effect of <strong>the</strong> two biases. Only in <strong>the</strong><br />

restrictive scenario where both biases are zero (cell 5), will firm j‟s <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> fully<br />

capture its abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>. In all o<strong>the</strong>r cases, <strong>the</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> of firm j will be biased.<br />

The bias in firm j‟s <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> is negative when <strong>the</strong> income distortion of <strong>the</strong> benchmark<br />

firms is positive (cell 4), or <strong>the</strong> deviation in firm j‟s operating policies is negative (cell 2), or both<br />

(cell 1). However, <strong>the</strong> bias in firm j‟s <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> is positive when <strong>the</strong> income distortion<br />

of <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms is negative (cell 6), or <strong>the</strong> deviation in firm j‟s operating policies is<br />

negative (cell 8), or both (cell 9). If <strong>the</strong> bias in <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> is extreme, <strong>the</strong> type I error<br />

for <strong>the</strong> null of earnings management will be high for firms not engaging in earnings management.<br />

Alternatively, if firms are managing earnings downward (upward) <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> bias in <strong>unexpected</strong><br />

28


<strong>accruals</strong> is highly positive (negative), <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will be attenuated. As a result,<br />

<strong>the</strong> type II error for <strong>the</strong> null of earnings management for this type of firm will be high.<br />

4.2 Modified version of <strong>the</strong> Dechow <strong>and</strong> Dichev (2002) model<br />

In <strong>the</strong> Dechow <strong>and</strong> Dichev (2002) model (hereafter DD model), working capital <strong>accruals</strong> are<br />

regressed on lag, current, <strong>and</strong> lead cash flow from operations. After some slight modifications, it<br />

can be reconciled with <strong>the</strong> encompassing model. Specifically, I divide <strong>the</strong> OIB of<br />

29<br />

t t<br />

WC DA<br />

in Table 3 by C of <strong>the</strong> same period <strong>and</strong> divide DA by <strong>the</strong> lagged non-current operating assets.<br />

Re-arranging yields<br />

t t u u u u, t1 u, t<br />

WC DA C C C NCO NCO<br />

(14)<br />

j j 0, t 1, t t 1, j 2, t t, j 3, t t 1, j 5, t j 5, t j t, j<br />

This modified version of <strong>the</strong> DD model mirrors <strong>the</strong> encompassing model. The only difference<br />

between <strong>the</strong>m is that underlying lead, lag, <strong>and</strong> current cash flow from operations (C) are used in<br />

<strong>the</strong> former model to capture working capital <strong>accruals</strong>, while lead, lag, <strong>and</strong> current underlying<br />

revenue are used in <strong>the</strong> latter model. This will lead to different parameter estimates (i.e., 1,t , 2,t ,<br />

<strong>and</strong> 3,t will differ from 1,t , 2,t , <strong>and</strong> 3,t respectively) but it will not affect <strong>the</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong><br />

<strong>accruals</strong> which capture <strong>the</strong> heterogeneity in parameters. Since <strong>the</strong> interest in identifying earnings<br />

management lies in extracting <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> <strong>and</strong> not in estimating <strong>the</strong> parameters, both<br />

models are equivalent when it comes to detecting earnings management.<br />

Despite this, one may find <strong>the</strong> modified version of <strong>the</strong> DD model to be more empirically<br />

desirable because it is more difficult to extrapolate unbiased or underlying revenue relative to<br />

underlying cash flow. While both revenue <strong>and</strong> cash flow from operations are subject to<br />

management, <strong>the</strong> latter seems to be subject to relatively less management than <strong>the</strong> former. As a


esult, <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> measures from <strong>the</strong> modified version of <strong>the</strong> DD model are superior to<br />

those from <strong>the</strong> encompassing model, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> degree of superiority depends on <strong>the</strong> extent that to<br />

which measurement errors in revenue are greater than measurement errors in cash flow in<br />

measuring <strong>the</strong>ir respective underlying items.<br />

4.3 Jones model<br />

To derive <strong>the</strong> Jones model, one can first re-parameterize <strong>the</strong> encompassing model in (11) as<br />

where<br />

WC DA REV REV REV<br />

t t u, t u, t1 u, t1<br />

j j 0, t 1, t j 2, t j 3, t j<br />

NCO NCO <br />

u, t1 u, t<br />

4, t j 5, t j t, j<br />

,<br />

1, t 1, t<br />

<br />

<br />

,<br />

2, t 1, t 2, t<br />

<br />

3, t 1, t 2, t 3, t<br />

This model is econometrically identical to <strong>the</strong> encompassing model in (11) but with different<br />

combinations of parameters being estimated (Bewley 1979). 18 If one imposes <strong>the</strong> following<br />

restrictions 2, t 1,<br />

t<br />

where<br />

, 3, 0<br />

t , <strong>and</strong> 5, t 0<br />

, model (15) will be reduced to<br />

t t u, t u, t1<br />

WC DA REV NCO<br />

j j 0, t 1, t j 4, t j t, j<br />

(15)<br />

<br />

(16)<br />

<br />

REV NCO<br />

(17)<br />

u, t1 u, t1<br />

t, j 0, t, j 0, t 1, t, j 1, t j 4, t, j 4, t j<br />

This model is commonly referred to as <strong>the</strong> Jones model, as it was originally employed in Jones<br />

(1991) to extract <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> to test <strong>the</strong> extent of downward income management during<br />

import relief investigations. It is simply a version of <strong>the</strong> encompassing model in (11) with<br />

restrictions 2, t 1,<br />

t<br />

, 3, 0<br />

t , <strong>and</strong> 5, t 0<br />

.<br />

18 This is only one possible transformation, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>re are o<strong>the</strong>r possible transformations.<br />

30


These restrictions respectively imply that (a) <strong>the</strong>re is no change in accrual policy <strong>and</strong> profit<br />

margin of benchmark firms between period t–1 <strong>and</strong> t, (b) <strong>the</strong> deferred component of normal<br />

working capital <strong>accruals</strong> is zero (i.e., deferred expenses <strong>and</strong> revenue are zero), <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>re is no<br />

distortion in <strong>the</strong> working capital <strong>accruals</strong> of <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms, <strong>and</strong> (c) <strong>the</strong>re is no distortion in<br />

<strong>the</strong> benchmark firms‟ depreciation expenses. Under <strong>the</strong>se restrictions, <strong>the</strong> Jones model<br />

<strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> for firm j will be totally attributed to firm j‟s heterogeneity in parameters.<br />

All <strong>the</strong> implications discussed in <strong>the</strong> encompassing model will apply.<br />

However, if any of <strong>the</strong> 2, t 1,<br />

t,<br />

3, t 0<br />

, <strong>and</strong> 5, t 0<br />

31<br />

restrictions do not hold, <strong>the</strong> Jones model<br />

will be mis-specified <strong>and</strong> suffer from correlated omitted variable bias. Specifically, one period<br />

ahead revenue growth, one period ahead revenue, <strong>and</strong> current non-current operating assets are<br />

<strong>the</strong> relevant variables omitted from <strong>the</strong> model, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>y will be captured by <strong>the</strong> disturbance term<br />

t, j.<br />

Since revenue is likely to be serially correlated with past revenue, <strong>the</strong> estimate of 1,t is<br />

likely to be biased. Similarly, 4,t is likely to be biased as non-current operating assets are likely<br />

to be serially correlated. The direction of this omitted variable bias will be determined by <strong>the</strong><br />

(positive or negative) signs of 2,t , 3,t , <strong>and</strong> 5,t <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> correlation between <strong>the</strong> omitted<br />

variables <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> included variables (see Greene 2000 for details).<br />

If <strong>the</strong> omitted variables do not correlate with <strong>the</strong> included variables, <strong>the</strong> parameters 1,t <strong>and</strong> 4,t<br />

will not be biased. However, <strong>the</strong>y will still contaminate <strong>the</strong> Jones model <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong>,


<strong>and</strong> this contamination from omitted variables is in addition to <strong>the</strong> problems of heterogeneity. To<br />

see this, let us re-arrange <strong>the</strong> Jones disturbance item in (17) as follows<br />

<br />

REV NCO<br />

u, t1 u, t1<br />

t, j 0, t, j 0, t 1, t, j 1, t j 4, t, j 4, t j<br />

PM a REV da PM REV<br />

u, t t u, t t u, t1 u, t<br />

TWC j TWC j<br />

t dTWC u, t1 OI<br />

t u, t1<br />

ddTWC OI<br />

TWC TWC NCO NCO NCO <br />

<br />

m OI dm OI m dm gm DA<br />

t u, t1 t u, t1 t t t u, t1<br />

Jones model <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> do capture all portions of abnormal working capital <strong>accruals</strong><br />

aside from <strong>the</strong> reversal of abnormal depreciation expenses from previous period; this is shown in<br />

<strong>the</strong> fourth line of (18). However, <strong>the</strong>y are also severely contaminated by a significant portion of<br />

normal <strong>accruals</strong> that are in addition to <strong>the</strong> heterogeneity problem encountered by <strong>the</strong><br />

encompassing model (<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>se heterogeneity problems are shown in <strong>the</strong> first line in (18)).<br />

Since <strong>the</strong> heterogeneity problem is extensively discussed in section 4.1, I will only discuss <strong>the</strong><br />

additional problems specific to Jones model <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong>.<br />

Specifically, <strong>the</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong>‟ contamination can be attributed to three sources. The first<br />

source of contamination comes from <strong>the</strong> change in real profit margin from firm j in period t. This<br />

u, t t u, t<br />

is shown in <strong>the</strong> second line of (18) as PM a REV <strong>and</strong> is also equal to <strong>the</strong> growth in<br />

TWC j<br />

u, t u, t<br />

profit margin ( PM PM ) times <strong>the</strong> initiated accrued component of working capital<br />

ut ,<br />

<strong>accruals</strong> ( OIB ). Thus, a 1% growth in profit margin will bias <strong>the</strong> Jones <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong><br />

t 1<br />

upward. The amount of this bias will be equivalent to 1% of <strong>the</strong> accrual component of working<br />

capital <strong>accruals</strong> which are initiated in that period. The opposite is true if <strong>the</strong>re is a negative<br />

growth in profit margin.<br />

(18)<br />

32


The second source of contamination comes from <strong>the</strong> change in accrual policy for firm j in period<br />

t. This is shown in <strong>the</strong> second line of (18) as<br />

t u, t1 u, t<br />

TWC j<br />

33<br />

da PM REV <strong>and</strong> is also equal to <strong>the</strong><br />

changes in <strong>accruals</strong> policy ( da ) times operating income before depreciation <strong>and</strong> amortization<br />

t<br />

TWC<br />

(OIB). If <strong>the</strong> proportion of accrual component of working capital <strong>accruals</strong> embedded in OIB<br />

increases by 1% (i.e. a relaxation in accrual policy), <strong>the</strong> Jones <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will be biased<br />

upward <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> magnitude of this bias will be equal to 1% of OIB. The opposite argument can<br />

be made when <strong>the</strong>re is a restriction in accrual policy.<br />

Finally, <strong>the</strong> third source of contamination comes from <strong>the</strong> magnitude of deferred component<br />

<strong>accruals</strong> which are attributable to deferred revenue <strong>and</strong> deferred expenses (i.e., <strong>the</strong> entire third<br />

line in (18)). The Jones model only considers <strong>the</strong> accrued component of working capital <strong>accruals</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> totally ignores <strong>the</strong> deferred component. As a result, a positive deferred component of<br />

<strong>accruals</strong> will bias Jones model <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> upward by its amount <strong>and</strong> vice versa for a<br />

negative deferred component of <strong>accruals</strong>.<br />

Hence, in addition to <strong>the</strong> heterogeneity problem, <strong>the</strong> Jones <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> are fur<strong>the</strong>r<br />

contaminated by a significant portion of normal <strong>accruals</strong>. This contamination can be attributed to<br />

three sources – changes in profit margin, changes in accrual policy, <strong>and</strong> deferred component of<br />

<strong>accruals</strong>. If any of <strong>the</strong>se contaminations are extreme, firms that are not engaging in earnings<br />

management will be classified as extreme earnings managers. Ceteris paribus, <strong>the</strong>y will be mis-<br />

classified as extremely aggressive if any or all of <strong>the</strong>se factors is in <strong>the</strong> positive direction, <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong>y will be mis-classified as extremely conservative if any or all of <strong>the</strong>se factors are in <strong>the</strong><br />

negative direction. The scenario of extreme change in profit margin supports <strong>the</strong> explanation for


<strong>the</strong> finding in Dechow et al. (1995) that <strong>the</strong> null of no earnings management is rejected at rates<br />

exceeding <strong>the</strong> specified test-levels when applied to firms with extreme performances. However,<br />

this paper also suggests two o<strong>the</strong>r scenarios in which <strong>the</strong> Jones model is likely to be mis-<br />

specified <strong>and</strong> in which type I error for <strong>the</strong> null of no earnings management is likely to be high.<br />

For aggressive or conservative firms, <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will be attenuated when any or all of<br />

<strong>the</strong> three sources of contamination is extreme in <strong>the</strong> opposite direction of <strong>the</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>.<br />

In particular, <strong>the</strong> positive abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> of aggressive firms will be attenuated by a decrease<br />

in profit margin, a restriction of accrual policy, <strong>and</strong>/or a negative deferred component of <strong>accruals</strong>.<br />

The opposite is true for conservative firms when <strong>the</strong>re is an increase in profit margin, a<br />

relaxation in accrual policy, <strong>and</strong>/or <strong>the</strong> positive deferred component of <strong>accruals</strong> is negative.<br />

These contaminations of normal <strong>accruals</strong> bias <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> toward zero, which could be a<br />

plausible explanation for <strong>the</strong> finding in Dechow et at (1995) that <strong>the</strong> Jones-type model has<br />

relatively low power to detect earnings managements of economically plausible magnitudes.<br />

4.4 Modified Jones model<br />

The very important assumption in <strong>the</strong> Jones model is that revenue is non-manipulated (indexed<br />

by <strong>the</strong> superscript u) in both <strong>the</strong> estimation <strong>and</strong> event periods. Since underlying revenue is<br />

unobservable, Dechow et al. (1995) used changes in cash revenue, extrapolated as <strong>the</strong> difference<br />

between changes in reported revenue <strong>and</strong> changes in accounts receivable, instead. Hence, <strong>the</strong>y<br />

modified <strong>the</strong> Jones model to<br />

, 1<br />

WC DA REV REC NCO<br />

(19)<br />

t t m m t t m u t m<br />

j j 0, t 1, t 2, t t, j<br />

34


Even if <strong>the</strong> use of changes in cash revenue eliminates <strong>the</strong> problem of measurement errors in<br />

explanatory variables, <strong>the</strong> modified Jones model still suffers from <strong>the</strong> same omitted variables<br />

problem as <strong>the</strong> Jones model. 19 As a result, <strong>the</strong> modified Jones <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will be<br />

contaminated by normal <strong>accruals</strong> that are in addition to <strong>the</strong> heterogeneity in parameters problem<br />

present in <strong>the</strong> encompassing model.<br />

4.5 Ball <strong>and</strong> Shivakumar (2006) model<br />

Basu (1997) suggests that unrealized losses (gains) tend to be recognized in income when<br />

expected (realized). Ball <strong>and</strong> Shivakumar (2006) incorporated this asymmetric timeliness into <strong>the</strong><br />

modified Jones <strong>and</strong> modified DD models. The delayed recognition of unrealized gains can also<br />

be regarded as an earnings management practice that shifts <strong>the</strong> recognition of income from <strong>the</strong><br />

current period to future periods. In particular, it will affect<br />

dm OIB <strong>and</strong><br />

t<br />

TWC<br />

u, t 1<br />

t t<br />

WC DA in Table 3. These two items can be combined into one item,<br />

t<br />

NCO<br />

u, t 1<br />

35<br />

dm DA in<br />

dm OI , which<br />

t u, t1<br />

OI<br />

captures <strong>the</strong> distortion in operating income due to changes in <strong>the</strong> level of distortion. This item<br />

t u, t1 t u, t1<br />

can in turn be modified as <br />

dm OI Var Var D dm OI Var Var to reflect<br />

OI t t ccOI t t<br />

conditional conservatism. After re-parameterization, one yields <strong>the</strong> following<br />

t t<br />

WC DA 0, , X 3, D 4, VAR 5, D VAR ,<br />

(20)<br />

j j t i t i t t t t t t j<br />

19 The difference between changes in reported revenue <strong>and</strong> changes in receivables do not equate to cash revenue.<br />

Since changes in revenue (∆REV) consist of changes in deferred revenue (∆DREV), cash revenue (∆CREV), <strong>and</strong><br />

accrued revenue (∆AREV) <strong>and</strong> changes in accounts receivable (∆REC) are equal to accrued revenue (AREV) minus<br />

repayments (REPAY), one can show that: (∆REV t –∆REC t )= ∆CREV t +(∆DREV t +REPAY t –AREV t-1 ). Hence, (∆REV t –<br />

∆REC t )=∆CREV t only in <strong>the</strong> case where items in <strong>the</strong> bracket are all zero. Even if this restrictive case holds, <strong>the</strong> use<br />

of cash revenue to extrapolate underlying revenue need not have eliminated <strong>the</strong> measurement errors in explanatory<br />

variables problem found in <strong>the</strong> Jones model. This is because <strong>the</strong>re are at least two ways in which firms can manage<br />

cash revenue. First, managers can manage current cash revenue upward by recognizing <strong>the</strong> cash inflow associated<br />

with deferred revenue as cash revenue <strong>and</strong> vice versa for downward management. Second, managers can manage<br />

current cash revenue upward by recognizing <strong>the</strong> cash flow associated with previous accrued revenue as current cash<br />

revenue <strong>and</strong> vice versa for downward management.


The main explanatory variables in <strong>the</strong> model (Xi) vary depending on whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> base model is<br />

<strong>the</strong> modified Jones or <strong>the</strong> Dechow <strong>and</strong> Dichev (2002) model, D is equal to one if <strong>the</strong>re are<br />

unrealized losses (or bad news), <strong>and</strong> zero o<strong>the</strong>rwise, VAR is <strong>the</strong> exogenous variable that serves as<br />

a proxy for news, <strong>and</strong> 4, t j <strong>and</strong> 4 t, j 5<br />

t, j<br />

are <strong>the</strong> parameters that capture instances of good <strong>and</strong><br />

bad news, respectively. In <strong>the</strong> absence of a bias in accounting st<strong>and</strong>ards, conditional<br />

conservatism is a discretionary distortion <strong>and</strong> its incorporation into <strong>the</strong> Ball <strong>and</strong> Shivakumar<br />

model leads to more abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> being classified as expected. 20 As a result, <strong>unexpected</strong><br />

<strong>accruals</strong> capture a smaller proportion of abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> than a model that does not<br />

incorporate asymmetric timeliness.<br />

5 Correlation between normal <strong>and</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong><br />

5.1 Correlation illustration<br />

It may seem puzzling prima facie from <strong>the</strong> analysis in section 4 as to why <strong>the</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong><br />

<strong>accruals</strong> from well-specified models (like <strong>the</strong> encompassing model <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> modified version of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Dechow <strong>and</strong> Dichev (2002) model) are even contaminated. In this section, I show that such<br />

contamination in <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> is almost unavoidable as abnormal <strong>and</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong> are<br />

correlated <strong>and</strong> cannot be explicitly disentangled. To see this correlation, let us make two non-<br />

crucial assumptions – (a) <strong>accruals</strong> reverse in one period <strong>and</strong> (b) reported cash flow is unbiased.<br />

With <strong>the</strong>se assumptions, total <strong>accruals</strong> in expression (10) become<br />

where<br />

* *<br />

t ttt t N D<br />

TACC NACC DACC (21)<br />

NACC a CNI d CNI ,<br />

*<br />

t<br />

u, t u, t1<br />

DACC m CNI ,<br />

* ut , 1<br />

t<br />

20 Recall that <strong>the</strong> framework of my analysis ignores <strong>the</strong> role of accounting st<strong>and</strong>ard setting, see section 3.4 for details<br />

36


The item<br />

<br />

m m CNI<br />

, 1<br />

a a CNI d d CNI ,<br />

<br />

N u, t u, t1<br />

t t t<br />

<br />

D u t<br />

t t<br />

*<br />

NACC t is <strong>the</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong> in <strong>the</strong> absence of heterogeneity in <strong>the</strong> accrual (a) <strong>and</strong><br />

deferral (d) parameters, <strong>and</strong><br />

*<br />

DACC t is <strong>the</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> in <strong>the</strong> absence of heterogeneity in<br />

<strong>the</strong> earnings management parameter (m). The normal <strong>accruals</strong> ( ) <strong>and</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> ( D<br />

)<br />

due to heterogeneity in parameters are assumed to be independently <strong>and</strong> identically distributed.<br />

Income is assumed to grow at a constant rate (g) as follows:<br />

1 <br />

u, t u, t1<br />

CNI g CNI<br />

(22)<br />

With <strong>the</strong>se assumptions, <strong>the</strong> correlation between abnormal <strong>and</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong> is shown to be<br />

t t <br />

c orr NACC , DACC<br />

N<br />

t<br />

<br />

<br />

1 1 <br />

1 1 <br />

m g a d g<br />

<br />

m g a d g<br />

where is <strong>the</strong> adjustment factor for heterogeneity among observations. 21<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

D N<br />

var t var t<br />

1 1 1 <br />

<br />

* *<br />

var DACC <br />

t var NACC <br />

t <br />

The correlation between abnormal <strong>and</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong> is equal to positive or negative . The<br />

term serves as an adjustment factor for heterogeneity among observations. It is 1 when <strong>the</strong><br />

heterogeneity in parameters is absent (i.e., when <strong>the</strong>re is no deviation in accounting <strong>and</strong><br />

operating policies among observations). Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> direction of <strong>the</strong> correlation depends on<br />

<strong>the</strong> direction of earnings management (i.e., m) <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> direction of normal <strong>accruals</strong> (i.e., a–<br />

d(1+g)). For aggressive earnings management, <strong>the</strong> correlation will be positive if normal <strong>accruals</strong><br />

21 See Appendix 3 for derivation.<br />

(23)<br />

37<br />

t


are positive or negative if normal <strong>accruals</strong> are negative. The converse is true for conservative<br />

earnings management.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> absence of heterogeneity in parameters (i.e., =1), abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> <strong>and</strong> normal<br />

<strong>accruals</strong> are perfectly correlated ei<strong>the</strong>r in <strong>the</strong> same or opposite direction. Let us illustrate this<br />

perfect correlation with accrued revenue for which cash flow is realized one period after income<br />

recognition. In Table 5, this numerical example assumes that accrued revenue is $100 in year 1<br />

<strong>and</strong> it grows at 20% per year.<br />

[Table 5 about here]<br />

Panel A shows <strong>the</strong> journal entry for this transaction if it is accounted for unbiasedly <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

resulting <strong>accruals</strong> (which are <strong>the</strong> difference between initiated <strong>and</strong> reversed accounts receivable)<br />

are <strong>the</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong>. Panel B shows <strong>the</strong> journal entry for this transaction if it is accounted for<br />

conservatively such that no revenue is recognized until <strong>the</strong> cash flow is realized. Since <strong>the</strong><br />

resulting <strong>accruals</strong> from this conservative treatment are zero, <strong>the</strong> resulting abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> are<br />

thus -100% of normal <strong>accruals</strong>. The correlation between abnormal <strong>and</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong> in this<br />

scenario is thus –1. Finally, Panel C shows <strong>the</strong> journal entry for this transaction if it is accounted<br />

for aggressively such that 20% of <strong>the</strong> next period‟s accrued revenue is recognized (prematurely)<br />

in this period. Since <strong>the</strong> resulting <strong>accruals</strong> from this aggressive treatment are 24% higher than <strong>the</strong><br />

normal <strong>accruals</strong>, <strong>the</strong> resulting abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> are thus 24% of normal <strong>accruals</strong>. Hence, <strong>the</strong><br />

correlation between abnormal <strong>and</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong> in this scenario is 1. 22<br />

22 A similar example can be made for cross-sectional firms<br />

38


Hence, to manage earnings downward (upward), firms can delay (accelerate) <strong>the</strong> recognition of<br />

positive normal <strong>accruals</strong>. As a result, total <strong>accruals</strong> will be lower (higher) than <strong>the</strong> normal<br />

<strong>accruals</strong>, <strong>and</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> will be (negative) positive. If <strong>the</strong> same level of conservatism<br />

(aggression) is to be maintained across time or firms, more negative (positive) abnormal <strong>accruals</strong><br />

are needed as normal <strong>accruals</strong> increase. In such a setting of no heterogeneity in <strong>the</strong> parameters,<br />

<strong>the</strong>re will be a perfect negative (positive) correlation between abnormal <strong>and</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong>. 23<br />

5.2 Implications<br />

For well-specified models such as <strong>the</strong> encompassing model <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> modified version of <strong>the</strong><br />

Dechow <strong>and</strong> Dichev (2002) model, my analysis reveals <strong>the</strong>ir resulting <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> are<br />

contaminated by two factors – income distortion of <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms <strong>and</strong> deviation in<br />

operating policy between this firm <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms. One necessary condition for<br />

<strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> to fully capture abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> is that <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms‟ income on<br />

average should be neutral (i.e., m=0). It is no coincidence that this is also one of <strong>the</strong> necessary<br />

conditions that will result in a zero correlation between abnormal <strong>and</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong> among<br />

firms. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r h<strong>and</strong>, when <strong>the</strong> income of benchmark firms is on average biased in one<br />

direction (m≠0), abnormal <strong>and</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong> are correlated. It is also no coincidence that <strong>the</strong><br />

resulting <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> under such a condition fail to capture abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> in full 24 .<br />

23 The presence of heterogenity is likely to decrease this perfect correlation. In particular, <strong>the</strong> correlation between<br />

normal <strong>and</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> is an inverse function of <strong>the</strong> variation in parameters that capture accounting <strong>and</strong> firm<br />

policies among observations. For instance, if <strong>the</strong> variation in accounting (firm) policy is as large as <strong>the</strong> variation in<br />

abnormal (normal) <strong>accruals</strong> among observations, <strong>the</strong> absolute correlation will be reduced to 0.5. If <strong>the</strong> former<br />

variation is lower (larger) than <strong>the</strong> latter, it will be higher (lower) than <strong>the</strong> absolute value of 0.5. The matching<br />

procedure proposed by Kothari et al. (2004) is likely to decrease <strong>the</strong> heterogeneity <strong>and</strong> increase <strong>the</strong> correlation.<br />

24 See section 4.1 for details.<br />

39


Hence, <strong>the</strong> correlation between abnormal <strong>and</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong> could be a plausible explanation as<br />

to why even well-specified <strong>accruals</strong> models are powerful in detecting abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> only in<br />

very restrictive circumstances. When abnormal <strong>and</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong> are correlated, <strong>the</strong> expected<br />

component will unavoidably embed some abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>. As a result, <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong><br />

extracted from <strong>the</strong>se models will not capture abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> in full. Specifically, when <strong>the</strong>re<br />

is no heterogeneity between firms, <strong>the</strong> r-squared of <strong>the</strong>se models will be close to one <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

model fully explains <strong>the</strong> variation in <strong>accruals</strong> which consist of both abnormal <strong>and</strong> normal<br />

<strong>accruals</strong>. The resulting <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> will be close to zero even for serious earnings<br />

managers. Since <strong>the</strong> high r-squared of a model can be due to its ability in correctly attributing<br />

normal <strong>accruals</strong> as <strong>the</strong> expected component or incorrectly attributing abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> as <strong>the</strong><br />

expected component, this raises doubt over whe<strong>the</strong>r one should judge a model‟s ability to<br />

correctly extract abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> by its r-squared.<br />

In short, <strong>the</strong> correlation between abnormal <strong>and</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong> inevitably leads well-specified<br />

<strong>accruals</strong> models to incorrectly attribute abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> as <strong>the</strong> expected component <strong>and</strong> less<br />

well-specified <strong>accruals</strong> models to incorrectly attribute normal <strong>accruals</strong> as <strong>the</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong><br />

component. The zero conditional assumption imposed by ordinary least squares requires <strong>the</strong><br />

disturbance term to be uncorrelated with <strong>the</strong> explanatory variables. The correlation between<br />

abnormal <strong>and</strong> normal <strong>accruals</strong> exactly violates this assumption. As a result, <strong>the</strong> approach to<br />

identify earnings management via a least square disturbance term of <strong>the</strong> regression is likely to be<br />

problematic. This echoes <strong>the</strong> points made in McNicols (2000).<br />

40


6 Conclusion<br />

My analysis reveals that <strong>the</strong> factors that drive normal <strong>accruals</strong> are growth in income <strong>and</strong> changes<br />

in <strong>accruals</strong> <strong>and</strong> deferrals policies, while abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> are driven by growth in income <strong>and</strong> a<br />

change in accounting policies. Since income growth is <strong>the</strong> common driver for both <strong>accruals</strong>, <strong>the</strong><br />

two are inherently correlated. This inherent correlation violates <strong>the</strong> ordinary least squares zero<br />

conditional assumption (that <strong>the</strong> expected component is orthogonal to <strong>the</strong> disturbance term). As a<br />

result, even <strong>the</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> from well-specified accrual models are biased by two factors<br />

– income distortion in <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms involved in <strong>the</strong> estimation procedure <strong>and</strong> deviation in<br />

operating policies between <strong>the</strong> firm in question <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> benchmark firms.<br />

Researchers who use <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> to identify earnings management need to ensure that<br />

<strong>the</strong> correlation between normal <strong>and</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> is minimized. This can be achieved by<br />

employing <strong>the</strong> idea of <strong>the</strong> matching procedure in Kothari et al (2005) with three modifications.<br />

First, instead of utilizing <strong>the</strong> ill-specified Jones-type models, well-specified models like <strong>the</strong><br />

encompassing model or <strong>the</strong> modified version of <strong>the</strong> Dechow <strong>and</strong> Dichev (2002) model should be<br />

used. The latter model could be more empirically desirable if measurement errors are taken into<br />

account as revenue tends to be relatively inferior to cash flow in measuring <strong>the</strong>ir respective<br />

underlying items. Second, instead of matching firms on ROA alone, firms need to be matched by<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir operating policy. As shown in this paper, <strong>the</strong> drivers for this operating policy are profit<br />

margin, accrual policy, deferral policy, <strong>and</strong> economic depreciation rate. Finally, <strong>the</strong> additional<br />

criteria for <strong>the</strong> matching firms is that <strong>the</strong>ir income distortion should, on average, be zero or<br />

unbiased, i.e., <strong>the</strong>y have no incentives to systematically manage earnings.<br />

41


Alternatively, future research can move away from <strong>the</strong> <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> approach <strong>and</strong><br />

explore viable alternatives to extract abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>, such as ratio analysis. Despite <strong>the</strong><br />

finding in Beneish (1997) that a combination of changes in accounting ratios is better at<br />

detecting GAAP violations than <strong>the</strong> Jones model <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong>, his approach lacks<br />

popularity. 25 The first reason could be because his approach yields probability measure ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

than <strong>the</strong> conventional abnormal <strong>accruals</strong>, for which interpretation is more intuitive. The second<br />

reason could be because this approach is interested in overall <strong>accruals</strong> ra<strong>the</strong>r than specific<br />

<strong>accruals</strong>, <strong>and</strong> it is <strong>the</strong> overall <strong>and</strong> not <strong>the</strong> specific abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> that determine whe<strong>the</strong>r a<br />

firm is aggressive or conservative. Hence, it would be fruitful for future research to overcome<br />

<strong>the</strong>se two issues to develop a ratio analysis-based approach that extracts abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> from<br />

total <strong>accruals</strong>.<br />

25 Beneish (1997) examined changes in eight ratios – gross margin, depreciation, SG&A, sales growth, total <strong>accruals</strong><br />

to total assets, soft-assets to total assets ratio, inventory turnover, <strong>and</strong> receivables turnover.<br />

42


References<br />

Ball, R., Shivakumar, L., 2006. The role of <strong>accruals</strong> in asymmetrically timely gain <strong>and</strong> loss<br />

recognition. Journal of Accounting Research 44 (2), 207-242.<br />

Bartov, E., Gul, F.A., Tsui, J.S.L., 2000. Discretionary <strong>accruals</strong> models <strong>and</strong> audit qualifications.<br />

Journal of Accounting & Economics 30, 421-452.<br />

Basu, S., 1997. The conservatism principle <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> asymmetric timeliness of earnings. Journal of<br />

Accounting & Economics 24, 3-34.<br />

Beneish, M.D., 1997. Detecting GAAP violation: implications for <strong>assessing</strong> earnings<br />

management among firms with extreme financial performance. Journal of Accounting <strong>and</strong> Public<br />

Policy 16, 271-309.<br />

Bewley, R.A., 1979. The direct estimation of <strong>the</strong> equilibrium response in a linear model.<br />

Economic Letters 3, 257-261.<br />

Black, E.L., McCulloch, B.W., 2004. Earnings management relations of <strong>accruals</strong> components: a<br />

multi-period setting. Brigham Young University.<br />

Dechow, P., Kothari, S.P., Watts, R.L., 1998. The relation between earnings <strong>and</strong> cash flows.<br />

Journal of Accounting & Economics 25, 133-168.<br />

Dechow, P., Sloan, R., Sweeney, A., 1995. Detecting earnings management. The Accounting<br />

Review 70 (2), 193-225.<br />

Dechow, P.M., 1994. Accounting earnings <strong>and</strong> cash flows as measures of firm performance: The<br />

role of accounting <strong>accruals</strong>. Journal of Accounting & Economics 18, 3-42.<br />

Dechow, P.M., Dichev, I.D., 2002. The quality of <strong>accruals</strong> <strong>and</strong> earnings: <strong>the</strong> role of accrual<br />

estimation errors The Accounting Review 77 (Supplement 2002), 35-59.<br />

Dechow, P.M., Sloan, R.G., Sweeney, A.P., 1995. Detecting earnings management. The<br />

Accounting Review 70 (2), 193-225.<br />

Feltham, G.A., Ohlson, J.A., 1995. Valuation <strong>and</strong> clean surplus accounting for operating <strong>and</strong><br />

financial activities. Contemporary Accounting Research 11 (2), 689-731.<br />

Greene, W.H., 2000. Econometric analysis, 4th edn. Prentice-Hall, Inc.<br />

Gul, F.A., Tsui, J.S.L., Bartov, E., 2000. Discretionary <strong>accruals</strong> models <strong>and</strong> audit qualifications.<br />

Journal of Accounting & Economics 30, 421-452.<br />

Healy, P.M., M.Wahlen, J., 1999. A review of <strong>the</strong> earnings management literature <strong>and</strong> its<br />

implications for st<strong>and</strong>ard setting. Accounting Horizons 13 (4), 365-383.<br />

Hribar, P., Collins, D.W., 2002. Errors in estimating <strong>accruals</strong>: Implications for empirical research.<br />

Journal of Accounting Research 40 (1), 105-134.<br />

Jones, J., 1991. Earnings management during import relief investigations. Journal of Accounting<br />

Research 29 (2), 193-228.<br />

Kothari, S.P., Leone, A., Wasley, C., 2004. Performance matched discretionary accrual measures.<br />

Journal of Accounting & Economics 39 (163-197).<br />

43


Lai, C., 2009. The impact of accounting distortions on measures of performance, growth, <strong>and</strong><br />

valuation. University of New South Wales.<br />

McNichols, M.F., 2000. Research design issues in earnings management studies. Journal of<br />

Accounting <strong>and</strong> Public Policy 19.<br />

McVay, S., 2006. Earnings management using classification shifting. The Accounting Review 81,<br />

501-531.<br />

Penman, S., 2009. Financial statement analysis <strong>and</strong> security analysis, 4 th edn. McGraw-Hill Irwin.<br />

Richardson, S.A., Sloan, R.G., Soliman, M.T., Tuna, I., 2005. Accrual reliability, earnings<br />

persistence <strong>and</strong> stock prices. Journal of Accounting & Economics 39 (3), 437-485.<br />

Roychowdhury, S., 2006. Earnings management through real activities manipulation. Journal of<br />

Accounting & Economics 42 (3), 335-370.<br />

SFAC1, 1978. Objectives of financial reporting by business enterprises. In: Statement of<br />

Financial Accounting Concepts.<br />

SFAC2, 1980. Qualitative characteristics of accounting information. In: Statement of Financial<br />

Accounting Concepts.<br />

SFAC5, 1984. Recognition <strong>and</strong> eeasurement in financial statements of business enterprises. In:<br />

Statement of Financial Accounting Concepts.<br />

SFAC6, 1985. Elements of financial statements. In: Statement of Financial Accounting Concepts.<br />

Watts, R.L., Zimmerman, J.L., 1986. Positive accounting <strong>the</strong>ory. Prentice-Hall.<br />

44


Appendix 1: Derivation of Normal Accruals Model<br />

Starting with <strong>the</strong> expression (3) <strong>and</strong> rewriting income <strong>and</strong> cash flow interchangeably (see section<br />

3.1.1 for discussion), one yields <strong>the</strong> following<br />

where<br />

<br />

titit t <br />

T<br />

u, t u, t u, t u, t i u, t i<br />

TACC CNI CNI CF CF <br />

<br />

Adding <strong>and</strong> deducting<br />

i1<br />

T<br />

u, t u, t u, tiu, ti CNI tiCNItiCNItCNIt <br />

<br />

i1<br />

T<br />

t t u, t ti u, ti ti u, ti d tiatiCNIat CNI dt CNI <br />

<br />

<br />

i1<br />

T<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

t u, t ti u, ti ti u,<br />

ti t u, t<br />

at i CNI at CNI dt CNI<br />

dtiCNI <br />

i1<br />

a CNI CNI , a CNI CNI<br />

t u, t u, t<br />

titi t u, t u, t<br />

titi ti u, ti u, ti t t<br />

d CNI CNI , d CNI CNI<br />

a CNI ,<br />

t u, t1<br />

ti above equations yields <strong>the</strong> following:<br />

TACC<br />

ut ,<br />

<br />

T<br />

<br />

i1<br />

tiu, t1<br />

t<br />

ti u, ti u, ti t t<br />

t u, t1<br />

a CNI , d CNI , <strong>and</strong><br />

t<br />

ti <br />

u, t<br />

<br />

ti t <br />

u, ti t<br />

ti <br />

u, t1 <br />

t<br />

ti <br />

u, t1<br />

<br />

ti at u, t1 CNI<br />

ti at u, t1<br />

CNI <br />

ti d t<br />

u, ti CNI<br />

t<br />

dt i u, t<br />

CNI t d ti u, t1 CNI<br />

t<br />

dt i<br />

u, t1<br />

CNI <br />

ti d t<br />

u, t1 CNI<br />

ti dt u, t1<br />

CNI <br />

aCNIaCNIaCNIaCNI <br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

Rearranging <strong>the</strong> equations yields,<br />

TACC<br />

ut ,<br />

<br />

T<br />

<br />

i1<br />

ti tiu, t1<br />

t<br />

45<br />

d CNI from <strong>the</strong><br />

,<br />

<br />

, 1 <br />

, 1 <br />

, 1 <br />

, <br />

, 1 <br />

, <br />

, 1 <br />

, <br />

<br />

, 1<br />

<br />

t u t u t t t i u t t i u t u t i<br />

atiCNICNIatiatCNIatCNICNI <br />

<br />

t u t u t t i t u t t i u t i u t<br />

dtiCNICNIdtdtiCNIdtCNICNI <br />

T T<br />

T<br />

t u, t u, t1 t ti u, t1<br />

ti u, t1 u, ti atiCNICNIatiatCNIatCNICNI <br />

i1 i1<br />

<br />

<br />

T T T<br />

t u, t1 u, t ti t u, t1 ti u, ti u, t1<br />

d tiCNICNIdtdtiCNIdtCNICNI i1 i1 i1<br />

<br />

i1


If one relates<br />

rates<br />

CNI<br />

<br />

u, t i<br />

to<br />

CNI<br />

ut , 1<br />

i1<br />

i1<br />

1<br />

k<br />

k<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

1 g <br />

k1<br />

1<br />

g<br />

k1<br />

<br />

<strong>and</strong> relates<br />

CNI<br />

u, t i<br />

to<br />

CNI<br />

ut , 1<br />

respectively, one yields <strong>the</strong> following:<br />

46<br />

using time-varying growth<br />

T T T i1<br />

1 <br />

TACC a CNI CNI a a CNI<br />

a 1<br />

CNI<br />

<br />

u, t t u, t u, t1 t ti u, t1 ti u, t1<br />

tititt k<br />

<br />

i1 i1 i1 k1<br />

1<br />

g<br />

T T T i1<br />

t u, t1 u, t ti t u, t1 ti k u, t1<br />

<br />

dtiCNICNIdtdtiCNIdt1g1CNI <br />

It can be written as<br />

where<br />

a<br />

i1 i1 i1 k1<br />

<br />

CNI<br />

T ut ,<br />

t ti ut ,<br />

i1<br />

CNI<br />

da<br />

ga<br />

<br />

<br />

TACC a CNI CNI da ga CNI<br />

,<br />

d<br />

u, t t u, t u, t1 t t u, t1<br />

d CNI CNI dd gd CNI<br />

T ut ,<br />

t ti ut ,<br />

i1<br />

CNI<br />

t u, t1 u, t t t u, t1<br />

CNI<br />

CNICNI ,<br />

dd<br />

<br />

T u, t u, ti t ti t<br />

u, t u, ti i1<br />

CNI CNI<br />

CNI<br />

1 <br />

<br />

<br />

T u, ti i1<br />

t t 1<br />

u, tik i1 CNI k1<br />

1<br />

g<br />

CNICNI ,<br />

<br />

T u, ti u, t<br />

t t ti u, ti u, t<br />

i1<br />

CNI CNI<br />

u, ti 1<br />

CNI <br />

1 1<br />

i1 CNI<br />

<br />

k1<br />

<br />

T i<br />

t t<br />

k<br />

, gd u, t i g<br />

<br />

, , 1<br />

<br />

k u k u k<br />

g CNI CNI 1<br />

The difference between expression (24) <strong>and</strong> expression (5) is in <strong>the</strong> summation signs in <strong>the</strong><br />

parameters; <strong>the</strong>y are <strong>the</strong> direct result of <strong>accruals</strong> taking more than one period to reverse.<br />

Expression (24) will be reduced to expression (5) if T is restricted to 1. The proportion of<br />

underlying income in period t attributable to <strong>the</strong> initiated accrued (reversed deferred) component<br />

is<br />

t t<br />

a ( d ). The difference between this proportion <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> proportion of <strong>the</strong> reversed accrued<br />

(initiated deferred) component recognized in underlying income is measured by<br />

steady-state where credit <strong>and</strong> payable policies are constant,<br />

t<br />

da <strong>and</strong><br />

(24)<br />

t t<br />

da ( dd ). In <strong>the</strong><br />

t<br />

dd will be zero (i.e., <strong>the</strong><br />

proportion of <strong>the</strong> initiated component of <strong>accruals</strong> equals <strong>the</strong> proportion of <strong>the</strong> reversed<br />

component in <strong>the</strong> steady-state). Finally,<br />

t t<br />

ga ( gd ) captures <strong>the</strong> interaction between <strong>the</strong> reversed


accrued (initiated deferred) proportion of income <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> growth in past (forward) income. It can<br />

be seen as an adjustment term for <strong>accruals</strong> that take more than one period to reverse. They are<br />

zero when (a) <strong>the</strong>re is no growth in past <strong>and</strong> future income, or (b) no portion of income is<br />

deferred or prepaid in <strong>the</strong> past <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> future, or (c) when T is equal to one, where T is <strong>the</strong><br />

number of periods it takes <strong>the</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> to reverse.<br />

As in <strong>the</strong> implications from (5), expression (24) indicates that normal <strong>accruals</strong> comprise of<br />

accrued <strong>and</strong> deferred components, with each of <strong>the</strong>m respectively consisting of three parts. The<br />

first part of <strong>the</strong> accrued (deferred) component of normal <strong>accruals</strong> captures <strong>the</strong> interaction<br />

between short-term growth in income <strong>and</strong> proportions of accrued (deferred) component in<br />

current income. If any of <strong>the</strong> two factors is zero, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> first part of <strong>the</strong> accrued (deferred)<br />

component of normal <strong>accruals</strong> will be zero. The second part is attributed to <strong>the</strong> relaxation of<br />

credit (payable) policy. With <strong>the</strong> same level of income, firms can end up with higher magnitudes<br />

of accrued (deferred) components of <strong>accruals</strong> if a greater proportion of accrued revenue <strong>and</strong>/or<br />

expenses is recognized. The final part serves as an adjustment term for <strong>accruals</strong> which take more<br />

than one period to reverse.<br />

Finally, <strong>the</strong> above expression can be generalized to different categories of <strong>accruals</strong>. Let AC be a<br />

particular category of <strong>accruals</strong>, <strong>and</strong> EC is <strong>the</strong> income from <strong>the</strong> associated clean-surplus relation<br />

in Table 1. In our previous derivation AC represents TACC <strong>and</strong> EC will represent CNI. Likewise,<br />

if AC represents ∆NOA, <strong>the</strong>n EC will represent OI. One can show that for a given AC,<br />

where<br />

a<br />

EC<br />

T ut ,<br />

t ti ut ,<br />

i1<br />

EC<br />

da<br />

ga<br />

,<br />

d<br />

<br />

<br />

AC a EC EC da ga EC<br />

u, t t u, t u, t1 t t u, t1<br />

T ut ,<br />

t ti ut ,<br />

i1<br />

EC<br />

d EC EC dd gd EC<br />

EC<br />

ECEC ,<br />

dd<br />

<br />

T u, t u, ti t ti t<br />

u, t u, ti i1<br />

EC EC<br />

EC<br />

1 <br />

<br />

<br />

T u, ti i1<br />

t t 1<br />

u, tik i1 EC k1 1<br />

gEC<br />

t u, t1 u, t t t u, t1<br />

ECEC ,<br />

<br />

T u, ti u, t<br />

t t ti u, ti u, t<br />

i1<br />

EC EC<br />

u, ti 1<br />

EC <br />

1 1<br />

i1 EC<br />

<br />

k1<br />

<br />

T i<br />

t t<br />

k<br />

, gd u, t i g<br />

EC <br />

, , 1<br />

<br />

k u t k u t k<br />

g EC EC <br />

1<br />

EC<br />

(25)<br />

47


Appendix 2: Derivation of Abnormal Accruals Model<br />

If <strong>the</strong> income of a firm can be shifted between periods, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>y can be represented as<br />

t<br />

<br />

T<br />

u, t<br />

<br />

t, ts <br />

T<br />

u, ts th, t<br />

EC <br />

u, t<br />

s1 h1<br />

CNI CNI m CNI m CNI<br />

where m t1, t2<br />

is a parameter that represents <strong>the</strong> proportion of underlying income in future periods<br />

embedded in or shifted to period t‟s reported income. The first <strong>and</strong> second subscripts denote <strong>the</strong><br />

period in which <strong>the</strong> income is recognized <strong>and</strong> from which <strong>the</strong> income is borrowed, respectively.<br />

As <strong>the</strong> maximum that a firm can borrow from <strong>the</strong> future is what is available to lend, m jt , is<br />

smaller than 1. Zero, negative, <strong>and</strong> positive mtt , 1 signifies neutral, conservative, <strong>and</strong> aggressive<br />

accounting distortions in period t respectively.<br />

Adding <strong>and</strong> deducting <strong>the</strong> two items<br />

s1 s1<br />

<br />

T<br />

T<br />

th , t u, t<br />

t, tsu, t1<br />

m CNI<br />

<strong>and</strong> m CNI<br />

yields <strong>the</strong> following:<br />

h1<br />

s1<br />

T T T T<br />

t u, t t, ts u, ts th , t u, t t, ts u, t1 t, ts u, t1<br />

<br />

CNI CNI m CNI m CNI mCNImCNI s1 h1 h1 h1<br />

<br />

Relating<br />

T T<br />

t, ts u, t1 t, ts u, t1<br />

<br />

m CNI m CNI<br />

<br />

CNI<br />

<br />

u, t i<br />

to<br />

CNI<br />

i1<br />

k<br />

using time-varying growth rates 1 g <br />

ut , 1<br />

equation yields <strong>the</strong> following<br />

where<br />

<br />

T<br />

t u, t th, t u, t1 u, t<br />

<br />

CNI CNI m CNI CNI<br />

h1<br />

re-arranging <strong>the</strong><br />

T T T s1<br />

t, ts th , t u, t1 t, ts k u, t1<br />

m m CNI m 1 g 1 CNI (26)<br />

<br />

k1<br />

<br />

<br />

h1 h1 s1 k1<br />

<br />

CNI m CNI CNI dm CNI gm CNI<br />

u, t t u, t1 u, t t u, t1 t u, t1<br />

T<br />

t t, t h<br />

m m <br />

T T<br />

t t, tsth, t <br />

, dm m m <br />

s1<br />

<br />

T s1<br />

t t, ts k <br />

gm m 1g1 s1 k1<br />

<br />

s1 h1<br />

<br />

48


The portion of underlying income in current periods that is shifted to previous periods is<br />

measured by<br />

t<br />

m . If I aggregate <strong>the</strong> proportions of underlying income beyond period t shifted to<br />

period t <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> proportions of underlying income shifted from period t to periods before t,<br />

measures <strong>the</strong> deviation between <strong>the</strong>se two aggregated portions which is zero under steady-state<br />

conditions. Finally,<br />

49<br />

t<br />

dm<br />

t<br />

gm captures <strong>the</strong> interaction between <strong>the</strong> portion of income shifted to <strong>the</strong><br />

current period <strong>and</strong> future growth in income. It can be seen as an adjustment term for <strong>accruals</strong> that<br />

take more than one period to reverse. They are zero when (a) <strong>the</strong>re is no growth in future income,<br />

or (b) no portion of income is shifted from future underlying income to <strong>the</strong> current period, or (c)<br />

when T (<strong>the</strong> number of periods that it takes for <strong>accruals</strong> to reverse) is one. The main implication<br />

from <strong>the</strong> above expression is that <strong>the</strong> difference between reported <strong>and</strong> underlying income (i.e.,<br />

<strong>the</strong> accounting distortion in reported income) is attributed to three parts that respectively capture<br />

short-term growth, temporary accounting distortions, <strong>and</strong> long-term growth.<br />

The expression (26) can be generalized to operating income <strong>and</strong> financing income. For a given<br />

earnings component (EC) like CNI, OI, or NFE, <strong>the</strong> following is true<br />

where<br />

T<br />

t t, t h<br />

EC EC<br />

s1<br />

m m <br />

<br />

u, t u, t t u, t1 u, t t u, t1 t u, t1<br />

EC EC m EC EC dm EC gm EC (27)<br />

,<br />

T T<br />

t t, tsth, t <br />

dmEC mEC mEC<br />

<br />

s1 h1<br />

<br />

<br />

11 s1 k1<br />

<br />

T s1<br />

t t, ts k<br />

, gmEC mEC gEC<br />

<br />

Combining expression (25) <strong>and</strong> expression (27), one yields <strong>the</strong> following <strong>accruals</strong> model:<br />

AC a EC da ga EC<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

t t u, t t t u, t 1<br />

AC AC AC<br />

d EC dd gd EC<br />

t u, t1 t t u, t1<br />

AC AC AC<br />

t u, t1 t t u, t1 u, t<br />

mACEC dmAC gmAC EC CFCt CFC <br />

<br />

where AC is a particular <strong>accruals</strong> component, <strong>and</strong> EC <strong>and</strong> CFC are <strong>the</strong> income <strong>and</strong> cash flow<br />

components from <strong>the</strong> associated clean-surplus relation in Table 1. This <strong>accruals</strong> model can be<br />

generalised to different categories of <strong>accruals</strong> with <strong>the</strong>ir associated clean-surplus flow<br />

components <strong>and</strong> parameters as shown in table 3.<br />

(28)


Appendix 3: Correlation between Abnormal <strong>and</strong> Normal Accruals<br />

If growth is assumed to grow at a constant rate g as follows<br />

This implies <strong>the</strong> following<br />

1 <br />

u, t u, t1<br />

CNI g CNI<br />

(29)<br />

u, t u, t1 u, t1 u, t<br />

CNI CNI g CNI g CNI<br />

<br />

u, t1 u, t1<br />

cov g CNI , g 1 g CNI <br />

2 ut , 1<br />

g 1 g var CNI <br />

cov , cov ,<br />

u, t u, t1<br />

CNI g CNI<br />

<br />

2 ut , 1<br />

g var CNI <br />

var var<br />

u, t1 CNI g u, t1<br />

g CNI <br />

2 2<br />

ut , 1<br />

g 1 g var CNI <br />

var var 1<br />

As a result, one can show that <strong>the</strong> correlation between normal <strong>and</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> in <strong>the</strong><br />

absence of deviation in accounting policy <strong>and</strong> fundamentals is as follows:<br />

*, * <br />

corr NDAC DACC<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

u, t u, t1 u, t1<br />

cov aCNI dCNI , mCNI <br />

u, t u, t1 u, t1<br />

var aCNI dCNI var mCNI <br />

u, t u, t1 u, t1 u, t1<br />

a m cov CNI , CNI d m cov CNI , CNI<br />

<br />

2 u, t 2 u, t1 u, t u, t12ut<br />

, 1<br />

avarCNIdvarCNI2adcov CNI , CNI <br />

<br />

m var CNI <br />

2 2 2<br />

a m g 1gdmg1g 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2<br />

2<br />

agdg1g2adg1gmg1g <br />

1 1<br />

2<br />

<br />

2<br />

<br />

2<br />

<br />

<br />

2 2<br />

<br />

a m g g d m g g<br />

1 2 1 1 <br />

<br />

<br />

2 2 2 4<br />

a d g a d g m g g<br />

<br />

<br />

1 1 <br />

1 1 <br />

m g a d g<br />

<br />

m g a d <br />

g<br />

<br />

50


Hence, <strong>the</strong> correlation between normal <strong>and</strong> abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> in <strong>the</strong> absence of heterogeneity is<br />

<br />

<br />

1 1 <br />

1 1 <br />

m g a d g<br />

m g a d g<br />

In <strong>the</strong> presence of heterogeneity, one can show that <strong>the</strong> correlation between normal <strong>and</strong> abnormal<br />

<strong>accruals</strong> is as follows:<br />

* N * D<br />

t t, t t<br />

corr NDAC DACC<br />

* N * D * N * D<br />

NDACt t DACCt t NDACt t DACCt t<br />

<br />

cov , var var <br />

* * * N *<br />

D<br />

NDACt DACCt NDACt tDACCt t cov , var var var var <br />

<br />

* NDAC *<br />

DACC <br />

<br />

N <br />

<br />

<br />

D<br />

cov , var <br />

t t t<br />

var t<br />

11 * * *<br />

*<br />

var NDACt var DACCt var NDACt<br />

<br />

var DACCt <br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

N D<br />

var var<br />

* *<br />

t t<br />

corr NDACt, DACCt<br />

<br />

1 1 <br />

<br />

* *<br />

var NDACt var DACCt<br />

<br />

1<br />

1<br />

1<br />

1<br />

51


Table 1: Accounting Identity<br />

Item Identity or clean surplus relation<br />

CASH CASH CASH C I F D <br />

CSE<br />

NCO<br />

NFO<br />

t t1 t t t t<br />

t t1 t<br />

CSE CSE CNI Dt<br />

NCO NCO I DA<br />

t t1 t<br />

t<br />

t t1 t<br />

NFO NFO NFE Ft<br />

NOA t t1 t<br />

NOA NOA OI C I <br />

TWC<br />

t t1 t<br />

TWC TWC OIB Ct<br />

t t<br />

Table 1 summarizes <strong>the</strong> accounting identities for cash (CASH), net operating asset (NOA), total working capital<br />

(TWC), non-current operating asset (NCO), net financing liability (NFO), <strong>and</strong> common shareholder equity (CSE). C<br />

is <strong>the</strong> cash flow from operations, I is <strong>the</strong> cash flow to investments for operations, F represents <strong>the</strong> cash flow from<br />

non-equity financing activities, D is <strong>the</strong> cash outflow from equity-financing activities. OI is <strong>the</strong> comprehensive<br />

operating income. OIB is <strong>the</strong> comprehensive operating income before depreciation <strong>and</strong> amortization. DA is <strong>the</strong><br />

comprehensive depreciation <strong>and</strong> amortization expenses. NFE is <strong>the</strong> comprehensive net financing expenses. CNI is<br />

comprehensive income<br />

52


Table 2: Summary of Accruals Components<br />

Accrued Component<br />

(if t superscript is less<br />

than <strong>the</strong> t subscript, i.e.,<br />

income recognition<br />

precedes cash flow<br />

realization)<br />

Deferred Component<br />

(if t superscript is more<br />

than <strong>the</strong> t subscript, i.e.,<br />

income recognition<br />

supersedes cash flow<br />

realization)<br />

Initiation at period t<br />

(if ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> t superscript or <strong>the</strong> t<br />

subscript has a “+” sign, i.e., an<br />

item is initiated in period t <strong>and</strong><br />

reversed in period t+i)<br />

t<br />

CNIt i<br />

t i<br />

CFt <br />

Reversal at period t<br />

(if ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> t superscript or <strong>the</strong> t<br />

subscript has a “-” sign, i.e., an<br />

item was initiated in period t-i<br />

<strong>and</strong> reversed in period t)<br />

t i<br />

CFt <br />

t<br />

CNIt i<br />

Table 2 summarizes <strong>the</strong> four <strong>accruals</strong> components depending on whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y are an accrued or deferred component<br />

or whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y are an initiation or reversal component.<br />

53


Table 3: Generalisation of Accruals Model to Different Categories of Accruals<br />

Accrual Drivers<br />

Total<br />

<strong>accruals</strong><br />

Total<br />

working<br />

capital<br />

<strong>accruals</strong><br />

Noncurrent<br />

operating<br />

<strong>accruals</strong><br />

Operating<br />

<strong>accruals</strong><br />

Financing<br />

<strong>accruals</strong><br />

Shortterm<br />

<strong>accruals</strong><br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

TACC a CNI da ga CNI<br />

t t u, t t t u, t1<br />

d CNI dd gd CNI<br />

t u, t1 t t u, t1<br />

t u, t1 t t u, t1<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

m CNI dm gm CNI<br />

<br />

TWC a OIB d OIB<br />

t t u, t t u, t1<br />

TWC TWC<br />

t daTWC t u, t1 gaTWC OIB t ddTWC t u, t1<br />

gdTWC OIB<br />

t<br />

mTWC u, t1 OIB<br />

t dmTWC t u, t1 gmTWC OIB Ct u<br />

Ct<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

NCO d DA dd gd DA<br />

t t u, t1 t t u, t1<br />

NCO NCO NCO<br />

t u, t1 t t u, t1u mNCODA dmNCO gmNCO DA It I <br />

<br />

t <br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

NOA a OI da ga OI<br />

t t u, t t t u, t1<br />

NOA NOA NOA<br />

d OI dd gd OI<br />

t u, t1 t t u, t1<br />

NOA NOA NOA<br />

t u, t1 t t u, t1<br />

mNOAOI dmNOA gmNOA OI <br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

FIN a NFE da ga NFE<br />

t t u, t t t u, t1<br />

FIN FIN FIN<br />

d NFE dd gd NFE<br />

t u, t1 t t u, t1<br />

FIN FIN FIN<br />

t u, t1 t t u, t1<br />

mFINNFE dmFIN gmFE NFE <br />

<br />

t u, t t u, t1 t u, t1 t u, t1<br />

aTWCOIB daTWCOIB dTWC OIB ddTWCOIB <br />

t u, t1 t u, t1u mTWC OIB dmTWCOIB Ct Ct<br />

<br />

u, t t u, t1 t t u, t1<br />

DA mNCODA dmNCO gmNCO DA <br />

<br />

t<br />

<br />

<br />

WC<br />

<br />

t <br />

DA <br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

Table 3 summarizes <strong>the</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> model applicable to total working capital <strong>accruals</strong> (∆TWC), non-current operating<br />

<strong>accruals</strong> (∆NCO), operating <strong>accruals</strong> (∆NOA), financing <strong>accruals</strong> (∆FIN), <strong>and</strong> short-term <strong>accruals</strong> (∆WC – DA).<br />

54


Table 4: Summary of <strong>the</strong> Bias in Unexpected Accruals for <strong>the</strong> Encompassing<br />

Model<br />

NACC NACC0 j<br />

Cell 1:<br />

t, j AbACC j<br />

NACC NACC0 j<br />

Cell 4:<br />

t, j AbACC j<br />

NACC NACC0 j<br />

Cell 7:<br />

Uncertain<br />

AbACC 0 AbACC 0 AbACC 0<br />

Cell 2:<br />

t, j AbACC j<br />

Cell 5:<br />

t, j AbACC j<br />

Cell 8:<br />

, AbACC t j j<br />

Cell 3:<br />

Uncertain<br />

Cell 6:<br />

t, j AbACC j<br />

Cell 9:<br />

, AbACC t j j<br />

Table 4 summarizes <strong>the</strong> bias in <strong>unexpected</strong> <strong>accruals</strong> relative to abnormal <strong>accruals</strong> for <strong>the</strong> encompassing model.<br />

WC DA REV REV REV NCO NCO <br />

t t u, t1 u, t u, t1 u, t1 u, t<br />

j j 0, t 1, t j 2, t j 3, t j 4, t j 5, t j t, j<br />

represents <strong>the</strong> error term extracted from <strong>the</strong> encompassing model.<br />

t, j<br />

NACC (<br />

j<br />

55<br />

AbACC ) represents <strong>the</strong><br />

j<br />

normal (abnormal) <strong>accruals</strong> based on <strong>the</strong> observation specific parameter from <strong>the</strong> encompassing model <strong>and</strong><br />

NACC ( AbACC ) represents <strong>the</strong> normal (abnormal) <strong>accruals</strong> based on <strong>the</strong> regression parameter from <strong>the</strong><br />

encompassing model.


Table 5: Illustration of <strong>the</strong> Correlation between Abnormal <strong>and</strong> Normal Accruals<br />

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11<br />

Panel A – Unbiased treatment of accrued revenue that will be received one period after<br />

Dr. Receivables 100 120 144 172.8 207.4 248.8 298.6 358.3 430.0 516.0 0.0<br />

Cr. Revenue 100 120 144 172.8 207.4 248.8 298.6 358.3 430.0 516.0 0.0<br />

Dr. Cash 0 100 120 144 172.8 207.4 248.8 298.6 358.3 430.0 516.0<br />

Cr. Receivables 0 100 120 144 172.8 207.4 248.8 298.6 358.3 430.0 516.0<br />

Total <strong>accruals</strong> 100 20 24 28.8 34.56 41.47 49.77 59.72 71.66 86.00 -515.98<br />

Normal 100 20 24 28.8 34.56 41.47 49.77 59.72 71.66 86.00 -515.98<br />

Abnormal 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Panel B – Conservative treatment of accrued revenue where no revenue is recognised till cash is received<br />

Dr. Receivables 0 0 0 0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0<br />

Cr. Revenue 0 100.0 120.0 144.0 172.8 207.4 248.8 298.6 358.3 430.0 516.0<br />

Dr. Cash 0 100.0 120.0 144.0 172.8 207.4 248.8 298.6 358.3 430.0 516.0<br />

Cr. Receivables 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Total <strong>accruals</strong> 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Normal 100 20 24 28.8 34.56 41.47 49.77 59.72 71.66 86.00 -515.98<br />

Abnormal -100 -20 -24 -28.8 -34.56 -41.47 -49.77 -59.72 -71.66 -86.00 515.98<br />

Panel C – Aggressive treatment of accrued revenue where 20% of next period‟s revenue is recognised in this period<br />

Dr. Receivables 124 148.8 178.56 214.27 257.13 308.6 370.3 444.3 533.2 639.8 0.0<br />

Cr. Revenue 124 148.8 178.56 214.27 257.13 308.6 370.3 444.3 533.2 639.8 0.0<br />

Dr. Cash 0 124 148.8 178.56 214.27 257.1 308.6 370.3 444.3 533.2 639.8<br />

Cr. Receivables 0 124 148.8 178.56 214.27 257.1 308.6 370.3 444.3 533.2 639.8<br />

Total <strong>accruals</strong> 124 24.8 29.76 35.71 42.85 51.43 61.71 74.05 88.86 106.64 -639.81<br />

Normal 100 20 24 28.8 34.56 41.47 49.77 59.72 71.66 86.00 -515.98<br />

Abnormal 24 4.8 5.76 6.91 8.29 9.95 11.94 14.33 17.20 20.64 -123.83<br />

This numerical example assumes that accrued revenue is $100 in year 1 <strong>and</strong> it grows at 20% per year. Panel A shows <strong>the</strong> journal entry for this transaction if it is<br />

accounted for unbiasedly. Panel B shows <strong>the</strong> journal entry for this transaction if it is accounted for conservatively such that no revenue is recognized until <strong>the</strong><br />

cash flow is realized. Finally, Panel C shows <strong>the</strong> journal entry for this transaction if it is accounted for aggressively such that 20% of <strong>the</strong> next period‟s accrued<br />

revenue is recognized (prematurely) in this period.<br />

56

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!