01.10.2013 Views

Report on the euro-mediterranean partnership 2005 - Femise

Report on the euro-mediterranean partnership 2005 - Femise

Report on the euro-mediterranean partnership 2005 - Femise

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

FEMISE REPORT ON THE<br />

EURO-MEDITERRANEAN PARTNERSHIP<br />

<strong>2005</strong><br />

Analysis and Proposals of <strong>the</strong><br />

Euro-Mediterranean Forum of Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Institutes<br />

Samir Radwan, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research Forum, Egypt<br />

Jean-Louis Reiffers, Institut de la Méditerranée, France<br />

Coordinators<br />

June 2006<br />

This text has been drafted with financial assistance<br />

from <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> European Communities.<br />

The views expressed herein are those of <strong>the</strong> authors<br />

and <strong>the</strong>refore in no way reflect <strong>the</strong> official opini<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Institut de la Méditerranée<br />

C A I S S E D E PA R G N E<br />

PROVENCE - ALPES - CORSE<br />

FEMISE<br />

<strong>2005</strong>


FEMISE REPORT ON THE<br />

EURO-MEDITERRANEAN PARTNERSHIP<br />

<strong>2005</strong><br />

Samir Radwan, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research Forum, Egypt<br />

Jean-Louis Reiffers, Institut de la Méditerranée, France<br />

Coordinators<br />

June 2006<br />

<strong>2005</strong><br />

This report was produced with financial support from <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> of European Communities. The<br />

opini<strong>on</strong>s expressed in this <str<strong>on</strong>g>Report</str<strong>on</strong>g> are those of <strong>the</strong> authors <strong>on</strong>ly and do not necessarily reflect <strong>the</strong> opini<strong>on</strong>s<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> of European Communities.


-ii-


Main redactors :<br />

FEMISE REPORT ON THE<br />

EURO-MEDITERRANEAN PARTNERSHIP<br />

<strong>2005</strong><br />

June 2006<br />

Frédéric Blanc Institut de la Méditerranée, France<br />

Nathalie Grand Institut de la Méditerranée, France<br />

Maryse Louis Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research Forum Egypt<br />

Yasmine Fahim Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research Forum Egypt<br />

List of <strong>the</strong> main <strong>Femise</strong> researches used in this report:<br />

FEM 21-31 : «Promoting Competitivness in <strong>the</strong> Micro and Small Enterprise Sector in MENA», leaded by Faculty<br />

of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Political Sciences, Cairo University, coord. Alia El-Mahdi, in collaborati<strong>on</strong> with INSEA<br />

(Morocco), Bogazici University (Turkey), C<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> and Research Institute (Leban<strong>on</strong>) ; December <strong>2005</strong><br />

FEM22-02 : «Impact of Liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of Trade in Services: Banking, Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s and Maritime Transport<br />

in Egypt, Morocco, Tunisia and Turkey», leaded by Bilkent University, Center for Internati<strong>on</strong>al Ec<strong>on</strong>omics,<br />

coord. Sübidey Togan in collaborati<strong>on</strong> with Faculty of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Political Science, Cairo University.<br />

(Egypt), INSEA (Morocco), University of Tunis (Tunisia) ; December <strong>2005</strong><br />

FEM22-06 : «The Informal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy Employment Impacts Of Trade Liberalisati<strong>on</strong> And Increased Competiti<strong>on</strong> In<br />

Export Markets: The North African Textile, Clothing And Footwear Sector», leaded by Federico Caffè Centre,<br />

Roskilde Univeristy Denmark, coord. Bruno Amoroso, Andrea Gallina, in collaborati<strong>on</strong> with CREAD (Algeria),<br />

INSEA (Morocco), University of Sussex (United Kingdom), University of Tunis, Tunisia ; October <strong>2005</strong><br />

FEM22-07 : «Integrati<strong>on</strong> and enlargement of <strong>the</strong> European Uni<strong>on</strong>, less<strong>on</strong>s for <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong>», Center for<br />

European Studies, Faculty of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Political Science, Cairo University, coord. Naglaa El Ehwany,<br />

November <strong>2005</strong><br />

FEM22-20 : «Flexibilité du travail et c<strong>on</strong>currence sur le marché des biens et services : impact sur les c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

de travail et le développement du secteur informel en Algérie, au Maroc et en Tunisie», leaded by ROSES,<br />

université de Paris I, coord. Gérard Duchêne, Boris Najman, in collaborati<strong>on</strong> with CREAD (Algeria), CREQ<br />

(Morocco) et ISTIS (Tunisia) ; November <strong>2005</strong><br />

FEM22-22 : «Identificati<strong>on</strong> des effets sur la croissance et l’emploi des mécanismes d’ajustement micro-éc<strong>on</strong>bomique de<br />

l’offre face à l’ouverture», leaded by CEFI, université de la Méditerranée, coord. Patricia Augier, Michael Gasiorek, in<br />

collaborati<strong>on</strong> with INSEA (Morocco), Sussex University (United Kingdom) ; September <strong>2005</strong><br />

FEM22-34 : «Les perspectives de changement sectoriel dans les pays méditerranéens: quels secteurs de croissance<br />

après l’industrie légère?», leaded by CEPII, coord. Agnes Chevalier, Jean-Raphael Chap<strong>on</strong>nière, and<br />

Marc Lautier, in collaborati<strong>on</strong> with CARE-Université de Rouen (France), CEPN-Université de Paris 13 (France),<br />

ESSEC Tunis (Tunisia), Hebrew University Jerusalem (Israel), Granada University (Spain) ; July <strong>2005</strong><br />

FEM22-36 : «Obstacles to South-South Integrati<strong>on</strong>, to trade and to foreign direct investment: <strong>the</strong> MENA countries<br />

case», leaded by CATT-Université de Pau, réseau EMMA, coord. Jacques Le Cacheux, in collaborati<strong>on</strong> with<br />

Granada University (Spain) ; October <strong>2005</strong><br />

FEM22-39 : «South-South Trade M<strong>on</strong>etary and Financial Integrati<strong>on</strong> and <strong>the</strong> Euro-Mediterranean Partnership:<br />

An Empirical Investigati<strong>on</strong>», leaded by Institute of Financial Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, American University of Beirut, Dir.<br />

Sim<strong>on</strong> Neaime ; June <strong>2005</strong><br />

-iii-


June 2006<br />

Members of <strong>the</strong> Steering Committee:<br />

Samir RADWAN Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research Forum Egypt<br />

Jean-Louis REIFFERS Institut de la Méditerranée France<br />

Nuhad ABDALLAH Academic Unit for Scientific Research ( AUSR) Syria<br />

Sergio ALESSANDRINI Université de Modène Italy<br />

Aziz Al KAZAZ Deutches Orient Institut University of Hamburg Germany<br />

Bruno AMOROSO Federico Caffe Center Roskilde University Denmark<br />

Slimane BEDRANI CREAD Algeria<br />

Gérard DUCHENE Université de Paris XII France<br />

Mahmoud EL JAFARI Al Quds University of Jerusalem Palestine<br />

Alia EL MAHDI MSA Université-Le Caire Egypt<br />

Michael GASIOREK Sussex University United Kingdom<br />

Alejandro LORCA CORRONS Universidad Aut<strong>on</strong>oma de Madrid Spain<br />

Samir MAKDISI Institute of Financial Ec<strong>on</strong>omics Am. Univ. in Beirut Leban<strong>on</strong><br />

Tuomo MELASUO University of Tampere TAPRI Finland<br />

Jan MICHALEK Department of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics Université de Varsovie Poland<br />

Cherif MONDHER ESC Sfax Tunisia<br />

Seyfeddin MUAZ Royal Scientific Society Jordan<br />

Lahcen OULAHJ Université Mohammed V Morocco<br />

Yilmaz ÖZKAN Center for Mediterranean Studies Turkey<br />

Khalid SEKKAT Université Libre de Bruxelles Belgium<br />

Alfred TOVIAS Le<strong>on</strong>ard Davis Institute of Internati<strong>on</strong>al Relati<strong>on</strong>s Israel<br />

Meine Pieter Van DIJK UNESCO-IHE Institute for Water educati<strong>on</strong> Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands<br />

-iv-


CONTENTS<br />

Introducti<strong>on</strong> . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . p.1<br />

I- The enterprises facing <strong>the</strong> opening . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . p.5<br />

1. Small entreprises, a new panacea? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . p.5<br />

2. The liberalisati<strong>on</strong>–employment relati<strong>on</strong>ship from <strong>the</strong> point of<br />

view of small enterprises . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.12<br />

3. Determinants of behaviour: informality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.17<br />

4. Behaviour Adjustments of enterprises and jobs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.20<br />

II- Adjustment of sector specialisati<strong>on</strong>s to modify dynamics . . . . . . . . . . . . . p.24<br />

1. A specific industrial path . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.24<br />

2. The impact of industrial strategies <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> liberalisati<strong>on</strong>-employment relati<strong>on</strong> . . . . . .p.26<br />

3. The textile, revealing industrial sector dynamic . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.32<br />

4. Services, relay opportunities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.46<br />

III- Regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong>: time for choices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . p.59<br />

1. Current internati<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong> of MPs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.59<br />

2. European integrati<strong>on</strong>, a model for regi<strong>on</strong>al initiatives in <strong>the</strong> South . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.67<br />

3. Migrati<strong>on</strong>s in <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean: <strong>the</strong> road for Deeper integrati<strong>on</strong> . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.80<br />

Notes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.91<br />

Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.93<br />

Annexes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . p.97<br />

Socio-ec<strong>on</strong>omic Indicators of MPs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.99<br />

Macro-ec<strong>on</strong>omic Indicators of MPs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.100<br />

FDI inflows . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.101<br />

Trade relati<strong>on</strong>s . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.102<br />

Modelisati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> impact of a South-South agreement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.103<br />

Modelisati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> impact of a North-South agreement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.104<br />

Modelisati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> impact of a multilateral liberalisati<strong>on</strong> . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .p.105<br />

-v-


-vi-


Samir Radwan, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research Forum, Egypt<br />

Jean-Louis Reiffers, Institut de la Méditerranée, France<br />

INTRODUCTION<br />

The Mediterranean Regi<strong>on</strong> is <strong>on</strong>ce again<br />

at a turning point. Ten years ago, <strong>the</strong><br />

Barcel<strong>on</strong>a process had created a new<br />

framework for North–South cooperati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

which also laid <strong>the</strong> foundati<strong>on</strong>s for<br />

South–South integrati<strong>on</strong>, and charted<br />

<strong>the</strong> way to build peace and prosperity.<br />

The present transiti<strong>on</strong> to a neighbourhood<br />

policy, in turn, creates opportunities<br />

and challenges. It is in this framework<br />

that <strong>Femise</strong> should examine <strong>the</strong><br />

results obtained and identify <strong>the</strong> requirements<br />

for a successful neighbourhood<br />

policy.<br />

With regard to <strong>the</strong> results obtained up<br />

to <strong>the</strong> present, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Femise</strong> report, written<br />

in February <strong>2005</strong>, <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> ten years<br />

that have elapsed since <strong>the</strong> Barcel<strong>on</strong>a<br />

process, took stock of <strong>the</strong> first ten years<br />

after Barcel<strong>on</strong>a, at <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic level.<br />

It is true that <strong>the</strong>se results did not meet<br />

expectati<strong>on</strong>s, nor were <strong>the</strong>y able to<br />

make <strong>the</strong> needed modificati<strong>on</strong>s to <strong>the</strong><br />

dynamic process in <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean<br />

countries, so as to give impetus to visible<br />

changes in <strong>the</strong> daily lives of stakeholders.<br />

However, <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>the</strong><br />

report focused <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> following facts:<br />

√ There are two inc<strong>on</strong>testable and<br />

positive facts that will serve as presuppositi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

in this report. The first is that<br />

a macroec<strong>on</strong>omic discipline has been<br />

achieved, which preserves <strong>the</strong> major<br />

Coordinators<br />

June 2006<br />

-1-<br />

macroec<strong>on</strong>omic equilibriums indispensable<br />

to building a new dynamic process<br />

in <strong>the</strong>se countries. It should be emphasised<br />

that <strong>the</strong>se achievements are not<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly reflected in figures (cf. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Report</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

<strong>2005</strong>), mainly in budgets, balances of<br />

payments, or inflati<strong>on</strong> levels, which protect<br />

<strong>the</strong> future, give <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean<br />

countries time to make <strong>the</strong> necessary<br />

modificati<strong>on</strong>s and allow Europe to think<br />

up effective support tools, but <strong>the</strong>y are<br />

also and no less importantly, now rooted<br />

in <strong>the</strong> expectati<strong>on</strong>s of stakeholders,<br />

mainly n<strong>on</strong>-locals. It is suffice to say,<br />

that even am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> most c<strong>on</strong>servative<br />

instituti<strong>on</strong>s, which evaluate countries in<br />

<strong>the</strong> world according to different criteria,<br />

<strong>the</strong> great majority of Mediterranean<br />

Countries are high <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> list in terms of<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

√ The sec<strong>on</strong>d positive point, which<br />

also gives us hope in <strong>the</strong> future of Euro-<br />

Mediterranean <strong>partnership</strong>, is <strong>the</strong> almost<br />

unfailing support that civil society in<br />

Euro-Med countries has given <strong>the</strong> process.<br />

Paradoxically, even harsh judgments,<br />

made <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> occasi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

tenth anniversary, indicate a form of<br />

irritati<strong>on</strong> with a promising tool, which<br />

is tardy in producing c<strong>on</strong>crete results.<br />

Today, this is what should be a priority:<br />

how can <strong>the</strong> efforts of <strong>the</strong> two coasts of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Mediterranean be made visible. How<br />

to make visible: acti<strong>on</strong>s taken as part of<br />

associati<strong>on</strong> agreements and <strong>the</strong> positive<br />

effects of <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>siderable adjustments.


In brief, help <strong>the</strong> stakeholder to seize <strong>the</strong><br />

impact of this process in <strong>the</strong>ir daily lives,<br />

ra<strong>the</strong>r than just <strong>the</strong> instituti<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

√ On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, internal factors,<br />

(<strong>the</strong> enlargement of Europe, c<strong>on</strong>tinued<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>flicts) and external<br />

factors (evoluti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> WTO, involving<br />

a generalised open ec<strong>on</strong>omy policy,<br />

which has diminished developments in<br />

<strong>the</strong> MPs and <strong>the</strong> opening up of China,<br />

mainly within <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>text of multi- fibre<br />

accords), and, at times, unforeseeable<br />

and at o<strong>the</strong>rs, ignored factors have weighed<br />

heavily <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> Euro-Mediterranean<br />

dynamic process. To manage <strong>the</strong>se c<strong>on</strong>sequences,<br />

macro ec<strong>on</strong>omic stability<br />

al<strong>on</strong>e will not be enough. It may be an<br />

indispensable foundati<strong>on</strong>, but it should<br />

be completed by impetus-giving elements.<br />

The ILO annual internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

report <strong>on</strong> world employment indicators<br />

emphasises that ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth al<strong>on</strong>e,<br />

will not be enough to meet global job<br />

needs.<br />

The idea of <strong>partnership</strong> was that by<br />

combining macroec<strong>on</strong>omic stability<br />

with a liberalisati<strong>on</strong> strategy, through<br />

<strong>the</strong> establishment of a free trade z<strong>on</strong>e<br />

with Europe, <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean countries<br />

would have <strong>the</strong> basic elements for<br />

development, to which <strong>the</strong> effects of<br />

induced investments would automatically<br />

be added. Such effects would be<br />

improved competitiveness in producti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

sector specialisati<strong>on</strong> and development,<br />

and improvement of regi<strong>on</strong>al relati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> south Mediterranean countries,<br />

which would place <strong>the</strong>m in a<br />

better positi<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> dynamic process.<br />

The internati<strong>on</strong>al community has not<br />

failed to emphasise this and has modified<br />

its expectati<strong>on</strong>s for <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong> and<br />

as a result, increased <strong>the</strong> movement.<br />

-2-<br />

It should be noted that this mechanism<br />

has been overestimated, as most of <strong>the</strong><br />

expected automatic relati<strong>on</strong>s have hardly<br />

progressed.<br />

Our report is intended to c<strong>on</strong>tinue this<br />

research. First, it takes macroec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

stabilisati<strong>on</strong> for granted, without rec<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

especially as <strong>2005</strong> has been<br />

marked by <strong>the</strong> energy crisis, which has<br />

made it too early to reach final c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

At <strong>the</strong> same time, it is part of<br />

<strong>the</strong> perspective of <strong>the</strong> inadequate equilibrium<br />

achieved at present, since <strong>the</strong><br />

pace of resolving <strong>the</strong> job problem is not<br />

satisfactory.<br />

The idea, <strong>the</strong>refore, is to identify <strong>the</strong> initial<br />

and present c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s that <strong>the</strong> stakeholders<br />

encounter, <strong>the</strong> specific reas<strong>on</strong>s<br />

that have led to <strong>the</strong> inadequate dynamic<br />

process promised by <strong>the</strong> associati<strong>on</strong><br />

agreements, while trying to highlight<br />

elements that could modify <strong>the</strong> growth<br />

paths and social adjustment forms. This<br />

questi<strong>on</strong> had been posed by <strong>Femise</strong><br />

in its last rest research programme. It<br />

had raised <strong>the</strong> questi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> supply<br />

capacities of <strong>the</strong> MPs in resp<strong>on</strong>se to <strong>the</strong><br />

demand generated by <strong>the</strong> liberalisati<strong>on</strong><br />

strategy, which was <strong>the</strong> maximisati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong> induced investments, expected when<br />

<strong>the</strong> process was put in place.<br />

In this report, and <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> basis of several<br />

research studies, we shall adopt as a<br />

hypo<strong>the</strong>sis, <strong>the</strong> sources of a new dynamic<br />

process in <strong>the</strong> renewed performance<br />

of stakeholders, in <strong>the</strong> first place, in<br />

<strong>the</strong> network of enterprises, as <strong>the</strong>y are<br />

<strong>the</strong> establishments that will provide <strong>the</strong><br />

jobs that are absolutely necessary to<br />

<strong>the</strong> equilibrium of <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>. However,<br />

<strong>the</strong>se enterprises develop in a special<br />

historical background, which can <strong>on</strong>ly


e modified slowly and has many c<strong>on</strong>s-<br />

traints. Therefore, in <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>on</strong>d place,<br />

we should identify <strong>the</strong>se c<strong>on</strong>straints,<br />

which result from <strong>the</strong> sector structure<br />

of <strong>the</strong>se enterprises, mainly in terms<br />

of opportunities. We should look for <strong>the</strong><br />

terms of specialisati<strong>on</strong> and <strong>the</strong> opportunities<br />

that can generate a better circle.<br />

This impetus may be well supported in<br />

<strong>the</strong> framework of regi<strong>on</strong>al agreements.<br />

This, in fact, is <strong>the</strong> very idea of Euro-<br />

Mediterranean <strong>partnership</strong>. Then, emerges<br />

<strong>the</strong> questi<strong>on</strong> of what type of North-<br />

South and South-South <strong>partnership</strong><br />

would be c<strong>on</strong>sistent with <strong>the</strong> initial 1995<br />

objectives and <strong>the</strong> present geo-political<br />

developments.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> first part, <strong>the</strong> report discusses<br />

several surveys carried out by network<br />

teams and <strong>the</strong> specific processing of<br />

surveys <strong>on</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>al enterprises, to better<br />

understand <strong>the</strong> performance of firms<br />

and <strong>the</strong> impact of liberalisati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong>m,<br />

particularly with regard to employment.<br />

Local industries are, to an extraordinary<br />

extent, still dominated by micro<br />

enterprises, which provide <strong>the</strong> better<br />

part of private employment. It is in <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

performance, c<strong>on</strong>straints and perspective<br />

that we can find <strong>the</strong> dynamics of<br />

employment. The budgetary measures<br />

in <strong>the</strong> taxati<strong>on</strong> policy of States make it<br />

imperative to understand performance,<br />

particularly with regard to distincti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

made between <strong>the</strong> formal and <strong>the</strong> informal<br />

sectors which, in <strong>Femise</strong> Studies,<br />

appear to be more blurred than previously<br />

thought.<br />

The sec<strong>on</strong>d part will make an analysis<br />

by sector of <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy of MPs, with<br />

emphasis <strong>on</strong> textiles. It is now clear<br />

that improved supply, which is indispen-<br />

-3-<br />

sable in view of <strong>the</strong> job c<strong>on</strong>straints in<br />

MPs, can not automatically result from<br />

<strong>the</strong> adopti<strong>on</strong> of a liberalisati<strong>on</strong> strategy.<br />

Specialisati<strong>on</strong> and <strong>the</strong> dynamics of <strong>the</strong><br />

professi<strong>on</strong>, at <strong>the</strong> European and internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

levels, are am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> main c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

of competitiveness and durability<br />

of <strong>the</strong> enterprises.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> Euro-Mediterranean regi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong><br />

present situati<strong>on</strong> of Mediterranean countries<br />

is largely due to <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong><br />

two basic sectors of <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omies of<br />

<strong>the</strong>se countries (in 1995 and at present)<br />

are, <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>e hand, agriculture,<br />

which for a l<strong>on</strong>g time has been marginalised<br />

in agreements and it is <strong>on</strong>ly now<br />

that it appears <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> agenda, and <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> textile-clothing industry,<br />

which has been drastically disrupted by<br />

<strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> multi-fibre agreements<br />

and <strong>the</strong> opening up of China.<br />

To address <strong>the</strong> questi<strong>on</strong> of how a new<br />

dynamic process that is more suited to<br />

<strong>the</strong> needs of <strong>the</strong> MPs can be launched,<br />

will inevitably lead us to <strong>the</strong> questi<strong>on</strong><br />

of agriculture, a subject that has been<br />

discussed by <strong>Femise</strong> in 2003 and which<br />

will not be dealt with in this report.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> of what comes after textiles,<br />

or at least after <strong>2005</strong>, also arises.<br />

Specialisati<strong>on</strong> opti<strong>on</strong>s, whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y are<br />

dictated by a forced adaptati<strong>on</strong> to <strong>the</strong><br />

changed c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of competitiveness<br />

at <strong>the</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>al and regi<strong>on</strong>al levels,<br />

or by industrial policy strategies, are<br />

not without effect <strong>on</strong> employment and<br />

growth in each country.<br />

As <strong>Femise</strong> has already pointed out, <strong>the</strong><br />

MPs should find <strong>the</strong>ir place in <strong>the</strong> most<br />

dynamic external markets, an adjustment<br />

which remains to be d<strong>on</strong>e by most<br />

of <strong>the</strong>m.


However, <strong>the</strong> competitiveness of export<br />

enterprises in MPs can not be an end in<br />

itself in view of <strong>the</strong> employment problem<br />

in <strong>the</strong>se countries. In additi<strong>on</strong> to<br />

working in sectors that generate rapid<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth, specialisati<strong>on</strong>s of MPs<br />

should allow for sufficient absorpti<strong>on</strong><br />

of employment, or at least, enough to<br />

maintain present unemployment levels.<br />

The adaptati<strong>on</strong> of industries to <strong>the</strong> new<br />

c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of competitiveness, at <strong>the</strong><br />

local and internati<strong>on</strong>al levels, may arise<br />

from voluntary industrial policies or sector<br />

reform. In this transiti<strong>on</strong>, producti<strong>on</strong><br />

factors are moved, leading to <strong>the</strong> loss of<br />

some jobs and <strong>the</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> of o<strong>the</strong>rs. For<br />

<strong>the</strong> MPs, <strong>the</strong> questi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> final results<br />

is undoubtedly <strong>the</strong> most important. Over<br />

and above <strong>the</strong> industrial sectors, some<br />

services will assume major importance<br />

and <strong>the</strong>ir liberalisati<strong>on</strong> is likely to modify<br />

some present processes.<br />

Third, <strong>the</strong> report deals with <strong>the</strong> questi<strong>on</strong><br />

of regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong>, in terms of<br />

<strong>the</strong> potential c<strong>on</strong>tained for <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

integrati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> South and <strong>the</strong> form<br />

Euro-Mediterranean and South integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

can take.<br />

At <strong>the</strong> strictly ec<strong>on</strong>omic level, it would<br />

be a mistake to think that <strong>the</strong> enlargement<br />

of Europe and more particularly,<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>flicts <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> sou<strong>the</strong>rn coasts<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean, do not affect stakeholders’<br />

expectati<strong>on</strong>s, and as a result,<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic flow. With <strong>the</strong> establishment<br />

of <strong>the</strong> new neighbourhood policy, <strong>the</strong><br />

shape of this integrati<strong>on</strong> will become a<br />

more pressing questi<strong>on</strong>. Should it be<br />

unilateral, multilateral or take <strong>the</strong> form<br />

of regi<strong>on</strong>al agreements between countries<br />

at <strong>the</strong> same development levels?<br />

Each of <strong>the</strong>se opti<strong>on</strong>s is expressed in a<br />

-4-<br />

specific way. A South-South integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

would involve reallocati<strong>on</strong> of specific<br />

factors that could be substantially different<br />

from those generated by integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

with Europe, for instance. In view of <strong>the</strong><br />

socio-ec<strong>on</strong>omic situati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> MPs,<br />

<strong>the</strong>y should not be allowed to shoulder<br />

<strong>the</strong> same readjustment costs several<br />

times. This leads to an in-depth c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sistency of <strong>the</strong> different<br />

agreements.<br />

Then, <strong>the</strong>re is <strong>the</strong> very under-estimated<br />

symbolic dimensi<strong>on</strong>: as we said in<br />

<strong>the</strong> introducti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> durability of <strong>the</strong><br />

Euro-Mediterranean regi<strong>on</strong> cannot be<br />

c<strong>on</strong>ceived of without civil society. It is<br />

this support of civil society that will be<br />

<strong>the</strong> most important mainspring of a<br />

rapid transiti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>on</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> right directi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

have (finally) been defined. This is why<br />

it is essential that associati<strong>on</strong> agreements,<br />

<strong>partnership</strong> and neighbourhood<br />

policy should be str<strong>on</strong>gly felt in <strong>the</strong> daily<br />

life of stakeholders. Then not <strong>on</strong>ly will<br />

European policy be <strong>the</strong> decisive factor,<br />

but also <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>al policy of MPs.<br />

Finally, <strong>the</strong> <strong>2005</strong> annual report deals<br />

with aspects of migrati<strong>on</strong>. Partnership<br />

seeks to create a z<strong>on</strong>e that maintains<br />

equilibrium, peace and prosperity that is<br />

to establish a de jure interdependence<br />

that will de facto link <strong>the</strong> two coasts.<br />

However, <strong>the</strong> disequilibrium between<br />

<strong>the</strong> possible circulati<strong>on</strong> of financial flows,<br />

commodity flows and human flows, <strong>the</strong><br />

latter being <strong>the</strong> most systematically restricted<br />

can <strong>on</strong>ly generate fricti<strong>on</strong>, ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

reallocati<strong>on</strong>s that are not optimal<br />

and bring out <strong>the</strong> partial character of<br />

<strong>the</strong> present tool. It could be said that, in<br />

order to allow <strong>partnership</strong> agreements<br />

to be felt in daily life, to win over public<br />

opini<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> South and to have <strong>the</strong> sup-


port that will enable <strong>the</strong> accelerati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

reforms, <strong>the</strong>re should be developments<br />

in <strong>the</strong> possibilities of human flows.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, at <strong>the</strong> strictly ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

level, time is needed to make substantial<br />

modificati<strong>on</strong>s in <strong>the</strong> anticipati<strong>on</strong>s of<br />

<strong>the</strong> internati<strong>on</strong>al community, in terms<br />

of work in <strong>the</strong> MPs. This will c<strong>on</strong>tinue<br />

to affect investment flows, especially as<br />

a subjective disadvantage will persist<br />

between <strong>the</strong>m and <strong>the</strong> countries of <strong>the</strong><br />

East (because a well known political project<br />

will c<strong>on</strong>tinue) or with China (because<br />

its weight generates unequalled ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

perspectives). In fact, <strong>the</strong> need for<br />

financial investments in small projects<br />

is important, as we shall see in <strong>the</strong> next<br />

part of this report. From this point of<br />

view, migrati<strong>on</strong> generates a resource:<br />

<strong>the</strong> funds that are sent back home by<br />

migrant workers (mainly in Europe),<br />

which leads us to think that <strong>the</strong>y could<br />

be an important lever to enhance <strong>the</strong><br />

growth paths.<br />

I- The enterprises facing <strong>the</strong> opening<br />

1. Small entreprises, a new panacea?<br />

Studying <strong>the</strong> performance of <strong>the</strong> MSE<br />

sector is not an easy task, as it requires<br />

facing (at least) two sets of challenges:<br />

(i) <strong>the</strong>oretical challenges, including definiti<strong>on</strong><br />

problems, framework designing,<br />

etc; and (ii) practical challenges, since<br />

studying this sector means studying<br />

more than 90% of <strong>the</strong> enterprises that<br />

exist in a country, most of <strong>the</strong>m are not<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly informal but also deeply integrated<br />

into <strong>the</strong> society that <strong>the</strong>y are hardly<br />

located physically.<br />

The need to accelerate ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth<br />

of most MPs has created <strong>the</strong> need to tap<br />

-5-<br />

new sources that would push those ec<strong>on</strong>omies<br />

forward. Given <strong>the</strong> prevalence<br />

of <strong>the</strong> MSE sectors in ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities,<br />

<strong>the</strong>y could represent this endogenous<br />

power that, if given <strong>the</strong> adequate<br />

support, can c<strong>on</strong>tribute significantly to<br />

sustainable growth. The MSE sector can<br />

also c<strong>on</strong>tribute to <strong>the</strong> soluti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

unemployment problem, be a channel<br />

of investment of small savings, and a<br />

source of enhancing <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omies’<br />

value added.<br />

It is against this backdrop that <strong>the</strong> idea<br />

of studying this sector has originated.<br />

Despite <strong>the</strong> many challenges that this<br />

would involve, it was thought worthwhile<br />

to attempt to provide adequate<br />

and targeted policies based <strong>on</strong> sound<br />

understanding of this sector’s dynamics<br />

if it is to realize its potential.<br />

With this belief, <strong>the</strong> FEMISE (toge<strong>the</strong>r<br />

with several o<strong>the</strong>r internati<strong>on</strong>al d<strong>on</strong>ors)<br />

have funded a large and pi<strong>on</strong>eering study<br />

<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> means to promote <strong>the</strong> competitiveness<br />

of this sector in four MPs: Egypt,<br />

Leban<strong>on</strong>, Morocco and Turkey. The study<br />

is based <strong>on</strong> a field survey of 5,000 micro<br />

and small enterprises operating in each<br />

of those countries (3,000 in <strong>the</strong> case<br />

of Leban<strong>on</strong>) and aims at understanding<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir characteristics, <strong>the</strong> impediments to<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir performance, <strong>the</strong>ir prospects and<br />

<strong>the</strong> determinants of <strong>the</strong>ir success.<br />

The main surveys of <strong>the</strong> MSE firms were<br />

c<strong>on</strong>ducted in <strong>the</strong> four countries between<br />

2001 (Turkey), 2002 (Morocco), and<br />

2003 (Egypt and Leban<strong>on</strong>) followed by<br />

a follow-up survey (except in <strong>the</strong> case<br />

of Leban<strong>on</strong>). The survey was based <strong>on</strong><br />

filling questi<strong>on</strong>naires at <strong>the</strong> enterprise<br />

level, at <strong>the</strong> entrepreneur level, and at<br />

<strong>the</strong> household level.


The database of <strong>the</strong>se surveys will allow<br />

better assessment of <strong>the</strong> performance of<br />

this sector and deeper understanding of<br />

its needs.<br />

A profile of <strong>the</strong> MSE sector in selected<br />

Mediterranean Countries<br />

The MSE sector, defined here as formal<br />

and informal enterprises employing 1-<br />

49 workers, represents <strong>the</strong> backb<strong>on</strong>e<br />

of <strong>the</strong> activities of <strong>the</strong> MPs ec<strong>on</strong>omies.<br />

This sector represents more than 90%<br />

of <strong>the</strong> enterprises, employing 60-70%<br />

of workers in <strong>the</strong>se countries and c<strong>on</strong>tributing<br />

from 30-50% of <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omies’<br />

value added.<br />

97% of <strong>the</strong> enterprises (formal and<br />

informal) in Egypt, are micro and small<br />

(employing from 1 to 49 workers), <strong>the</strong><br />

informal[1] <strong>on</strong>es c<strong>on</strong>stitute around 81%<br />

of this share. It is also to note that <strong>the</strong><br />

informal female workers represent <strong>on</strong>ly<br />

14% of <strong>the</strong> whole informal workers<br />

community, which is a relatively modest<br />

share given that females c<strong>on</strong>stitute 50%<br />

of <strong>the</strong> populati<strong>on</strong>[2]. The MSE sector in<br />

Egypt employs 62% of total formal and<br />

informal workers (88% informal workers<br />

vs. 23% of formal). In Turkey this<br />

sector represents 99.4% of <strong>the</strong> total<br />

number of enterprises, most of which<br />

are formal since registering <strong>the</strong> firm is<br />

an obligati<strong>on</strong> before setting up certain<br />

activities. This sector employs 73%<br />

of n<strong>on</strong>-agriculture workers and c<strong>on</strong>tributes<br />

64.8% of total value added. In<br />

Leban<strong>on</strong>, 96% of enterprises are ei<strong>the</strong>r<br />

micro (88%) or small (8%) accounting<br />

for more than 50% of total employment.<br />

In Morocco, micro and small enterprises<br />

represent 99.6% of total enterprises,<br />

and represents more than 70% of total<br />

employment.<br />

-6-<br />

Determinants of Success of <strong>the</strong> MSE<br />

Sector<br />

Success of <strong>the</strong> MSE sector does not <strong>on</strong>ly<br />

depend <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> good performance of<br />

<strong>the</strong> firm, or <strong>the</strong> educati<strong>on</strong> and training<br />

of <strong>the</strong> entrepreneurs. This sector does<br />

not functi<strong>on</strong> in a vacuum: macroec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

and business envir<strong>on</strong>ment has<br />

significant impact <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> performance<br />

of <strong>the</strong> MSEs. Prospects of <strong>the</strong> MSEs, as<br />

reflected in <strong>the</strong> Egyptian and Turkish<br />

surveys, have been greatly affected by<br />

<strong>the</strong> recessi<strong>on</strong> that both countries were<br />

undergoing. One may argue that this<br />

reflects <strong>on</strong>ly a short temporary period<br />

that should not be generalized, but <strong>the</strong><br />

fact that this sector is not meeting its<br />

growth potential still holds. In fact, both<br />

<strong>the</strong> performance of <strong>the</strong> firm and <strong>the</strong><br />

macroec<strong>on</strong>omic envir<strong>on</strong>ment in which it<br />

operates play a major role in <strong>the</strong> success<br />

or failure of this sector.<br />

In view of <strong>the</strong>se c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, this research<br />

programme adopted a combinati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

quantitative and qualitative approaches<br />

to data collecti<strong>on</strong> in order to capture<br />

both <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>text and dynamics of <strong>the</strong><br />

issue within a nati<strong>on</strong>al and comparative<br />

scope for <strong>the</strong> entire regi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The coming secti<strong>on</strong> will discuss <strong>the</strong><br />

determinants of success of this sector<br />

as identified by <strong>the</strong> entrepreneurs <strong>the</strong>mselves<br />

in Egypt, Leban<strong>on</strong>, Turkey and<br />

Morocco. This could make major c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

to <strong>the</strong> designing of policies in<br />

each of those countries.<br />

1. Formality[3] represents <strong>on</strong>e of <strong>the</strong><br />

major determinants of success of<br />

MSEs. The degree of informality varies<br />

depending <strong>on</strong> its definiti<strong>on</strong> and <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

regulati<strong>on</strong>s. In some countries such


as Turkey and Leban<strong>on</strong>, registrati<strong>on</strong><br />

is a requirement before undertaking<br />

some activities. However, in Egypt,<br />

where being registered is not a requirement,<br />

it was found that 80% of <strong>the</strong><br />

MSEs are informal. Being formal holds<br />

many benefits as it means better<br />

access to financial and administrative<br />

support, but most entrepreneurs find<br />

<strong>the</strong> procedures of registrati<strong>on</strong> very<br />

complicated, time c<strong>on</strong>suming and<br />

expensive, relative to <strong>the</strong> potential<br />

gains it may achieve.<br />

2. The presence of MSEs in Clusters<br />

could, generally, provide an enabling<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ment that enhances efficiency<br />

of firms through existence of different<br />

producti<strong>on</strong> complementary entities.<br />

Being in a cluster ensures <strong>the</strong> exchange<br />

of knowledge and experience,<br />

and provides business inter-linkages<br />

between <strong>the</strong> firms operating in <strong>the</strong><br />

same cluster community, which adds<br />

value to <strong>the</strong> performance of <strong>the</strong> firm<br />

through <strong>the</strong> growing social capital.<br />

Being in a cluster was found to be <strong>the</strong><br />

top priority determinant of success for<br />

MSEs in Egypt. In Leban<strong>on</strong>, however,<br />

<strong>the</strong> norm is reversed; MSEs that do<br />

not bel<strong>on</strong>g to a cluster achieve better<br />

performance levels. This is due<br />

to <strong>the</strong> nature of clusters in Leban<strong>on</strong>,<br />

which c<strong>on</strong>sists mainly of firms in <strong>the</strong><br />

same, or similar, line of business. As<br />

a result, a competitive envir<strong>on</strong>ment<br />

arises, restricting profits, and thus<br />

performance.<br />

3. All studies of MSEs have showed that<br />

being a male entrepreneur means a<br />

better performance of <strong>the</strong> firm than<br />

being a female. Regardless of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

educati<strong>on</strong>, training and experience<br />

(if any), female entrepreneurs are at<br />

-7-<br />

a disadvantaged positi<strong>on</strong> compared<br />

to males: <strong>the</strong>y face more difficulties<br />

in <strong>the</strong> market, in getting educati<strong>on</strong><br />

or training and in getting access to<br />

finance and o<strong>the</strong>r support services.<br />

Moreover, <strong>the</strong> woman’s role in <strong>the</strong><br />

household limits her ability to work<br />

l<strong>on</strong>ger hours in her business.<br />

4. The existence of an enabling business<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ment that ensures good<br />

working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>the</strong> availability of<br />

specialized workers, access to financial<br />

and n<strong>on</strong>-financial business services,<br />

enjoying fiscal incentives and<br />

limited competiti<strong>on</strong> from larger firms<br />

are regarded as essential tools to<br />

ensure <strong>the</strong> success of <strong>the</strong> enterprise.<br />

5. The success of MSEs depends <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

educati<strong>on</strong>al attainment of its entrepreneurs<br />

and <strong>the</strong> training and/or experience<br />

he/she gained. It was found in<br />

Morocco, Leban<strong>on</strong> and Turkey that <strong>the</strong><br />

best performing firms are those that<br />

are owned by educated entrepreneurs<br />

who received more than 10 years of<br />

educati<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>trarily, in Egypt, it was<br />

found that <strong>the</strong> years of educati<strong>on</strong><br />

have no effect <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> performance of<br />

<strong>the</strong> firm.<br />

6. Equally important than being educated<br />

is <strong>the</strong> formal vocati<strong>on</strong>al or technical<br />

training for entrepreneurs. In<br />

turkey <strong>on</strong>ly 10% of <strong>the</strong> entrepreneurs<br />

had formal technical or vocati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

educati<strong>on</strong>. In Egypt, <strong>the</strong> percentage<br />

of entrepreneurs who received technical<br />

educati<strong>on</strong> was 3.4% for <strong>the</strong><br />

males and 2.9% for <strong>the</strong> females.<br />

In Leban<strong>on</strong>, this percentage is 9%<br />

and 15% respectively. In Leban<strong>on</strong><br />

what matters most is not <strong>the</strong> vocati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

training (it had a negative


affect <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> performance of <strong>the</strong> firm)<br />

but entrepreneurs who have training<br />

apprenticeship experience do benefit<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir firms, which record better performance<br />

levels. This is true in all<br />

countries under c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> because<br />

this type of training is specialized<br />

and thus can be particularly relevant<br />

to <strong>the</strong> field of <strong>the</strong> firm.<br />

7. Having access to financial resources<br />

c<strong>on</strong>stitutes an important determinant<br />

of <strong>the</strong> success and <strong>the</strong> sustainability<br />

of MSEs. As denoted by <strong>the</strong> entrepreneurs,<br />

it is c<strong>on</strong>sidered <strong>on</strong>e of <strong>the</strong><br />

major challenges <strong>the</strong>y face: financial<br />

instituti<strong>on</strong>s are not apt to lend small<br />

enterprises due to <strong>the</strong> high risk associated<br />

with lending small unknown<br />

entrepreneurs and high transacti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

cost linked with small loans. As a c<strong>on</strong>sequence,<br />

it was found in <strong>the</strong> survey<br />

c<strong>on</strong>ducted in <strong>the</strong> four countries that<br />

a very small percentage of entrepreneurs<br />

rely <strong>on</strong> formal loans to finance<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir businesses, while most rely <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong>ir own savings or o<strong>the</strong>r sources of<br />

finance.<br />

8. Ano<strong>the</strong>r important determinant of<br />

success is <strong>the</strong> availability of <strong>the</strong> adequate<br />

infrastructure (such as roads,<br />

transportati<strong>on</strong>, electricity, water,<br />

sewage, etc.) and also <strong>the</strong> access to<br />

Table X1: Sources of Finance for MSEs<br />

-8-<br />

some machinery and advanced technology<br />

(especially for firms working<br />

in <strong>the</strong> industrial sector) that would<br />

increase productivity and ensures<br />

<strong>the</strong> sustainability of growth.<br />

Assessment of Performance: A<br />

Case study of <strong>the</strong> MSE sector in<br />

Egypt<br />

In order to highlight <strong>the</strong> growth dynamics<br />

of MSEs in Egypt, a Growth Index<br />

was c<strong>on</strong>structed (using <strong>the</strong> available<br />

data from <strong>the</strong> main survey (2003)),<br />

where data related to <strong>the</strong>ir performance<br />

was given in two points of time:<br />

survey time (2003) and <strong>on</strong>e year earlier<br />

(2002).<br />

The Growth Index[4] is composed of four<br />

growth-indicating variables: (i) value of<br />

invested capital; (ii) space of enterprise<br />

(iii) number of workers; and (iv) value of<br />

used raw materials. The Index was derived<br />

based <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> average change rate in<br />

<strong>the</strong> values of those combined variables<br />

at <strong>the</strong> survey time compared to <strong>the</strong> previous<br />

year. The growth-indicating variables,<br />

help in shedding some light <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

dynamic change that occurred during<br />

this period.<br />

On average, <strong>the</strong> MSEs growth rate did<br />

not exceed 2.2% between 2002 and<br />

Source of finance Egypt Leban<strong>on</strong> Turkey<br />

Inheritance 21.0 18.0 5.3<br />

Own savings 67.1 60.0 78.9<br />

Liquidati<strong>on</strong> of assets 3.6 3.8 1.9<br />

Formal loans 3.5 4.2 0.6<br />

Informal loans 2.6 2.5 8.8<br />

Own remittances 0.5 5.5 0.1<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong>, from research n° FEM21-31


2003. The growth index showed that<br />

more than half (52.2%) of <strong>the</strong> MSEs<br />

did not grow within that year. Most<br />

of <strong>the</strong> remaining MSEs (28.5%) deteriorated<br />

and <strong>on</strong>ly 19% had registered<br />

some growth. While 17% deteriorated<br />

by more than five percentage points,<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly 12% grew with more than five<br />

percentage points.<br />

Testing <strong>the</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ship between <strong>the</strong><br />

growth index and some of <strong>the</strong> characteristics<br />

of <strong>the</strong> MSEs can assess <strong>the</strong><br />

effect of those characteristics <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

potential growth of <strong>the</strong> sector. The<br />

results showed:<br />

√ In terms of ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity, firms<br />

working in <strong>the</strong> industry sector have<br />

achieved <strong>the</strong> highest average growth<br />

of 4.1%, compared to 3.8% growth<br />

in <strong>the</strong> services sector, and <strong>on</strong>ly 1.3%<br />

in <strong>the</strong> trade sector.<br />

√ On ano<strong>the</strong>r fr<strong>on</strong>t, it was found that<br />

15% of <strong>the</strong> MSEs working in <strong>the</strong><br />

services sector witnessed a growth<br />

of more than 5%, while <strong>on</strong>ly 10% of<br />

<strong>the</strong> MSEs working in <strong>the</strong> industrial<br />

sector achieved this growth rate.<br />

√ In terms of size, data showed that<br />

small enterprises employing 5 to 9<br />

workers have achieved <strong>the</strong> highest<br />

growth rate of 4.75%, while those<br />

employing 10-49 workers have deteriorated<br />

with 1.3%.<br />

√ Data showed that while almost half of<br />

<strong>the</strong> micro enterprises (1-4 workers)<br />

-9-<br />

did not grow, 30% have deteriorated<br />

and <strong>on</strong>ly 18% have achieved some<br />

growth.<br />

√ The picture has somewhat changed<br />

when c<strong>on</strong>sidering small firms (5-<br />

9 workers), where <strong>the</strong> percentage<br />

of firms that deteriorated is almost<br />

equal to those that have improved<br />

(25%).<br />

√ While most of <strong>the</strong> larger firms (80%)<br />

(10 to 49 workers) remained unchanged<br />

during that year, indicating that<br />

that kind of firms is more stable. The<br />

number of firms which deteriorated<br />

was larger than those that have<br />

improved, putting <strong>the</strong> growth rate<br />

of this group at <strong>the</strong> negative level<br />

(1.3%).<br />

√ In terms of invested capital, results<br />

showed that firms that have invested<br />

a capital between 5,000 and 20,000<br />

LE have achieved <strong>the</strong> highest growth<br />

rate of 4.4% while those that have<br />

invested less than 1,000 have achieved<br />

<strong>the</strong> lowest of almost 0.5%.<br />

√ One of <strong>the</strong> interesting results that<br />

were found is <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>e deriving from<br />

studying <strong>the</strong> relati<strong>on</strong> between <strong>the</strong><br />

growth index and formality. It was<br />

found that informal firms have achieved<br />

a higher average growth rate<br />

of 2.7% than those that are formal<br />

(1.1%).<br />

√ In terms of pattern of growth, it<br />

remains <strong>the</strong> same for formal and<br />

Table X2: Distributi<strong>on</strong> of MSEs according to <strong>the</strong> index categories<br />

Growth Index value


informal firms: half of both categories<br />

remain unchanged (52%); almost<br />

28% of <strong>the</strong> firms (ei<strong>the</strong>r formal or<br />

informal) deteriorated, and almost<br />

19% of <strong>the</strong>m (formal or informal)<br />

achieved some growth.<br />

To summarize, <strong>the</strong> best performing firms<br />

in Egypt were those:<br />

1. working in <strong>the</strong> industrial sector;<br />

2. with a number of workers between 5<br />

and 9;<br />

3. with an invested capital between LE<br />

5,000 and LE 20,000;<br />

4. and informal.<br />

Prospects of MSEs<br />

It is clear that <strong>the</strong> performance of MSEs<br />

and <strong>the</strong> envir<strong>on</strong>ment in which <strong>the</strong>y operate<br />

play a major role in how <strong>the</strong> entrepreneur<br />

perceives <strong>the</strong> future of his firm.<br />

The study used a Future Prospects Index<br />

to measure <strong>the</strong> percepti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> entrepreneurs<br />

in <strong>the</strong> MSE sector <strong>on</strong> how <strong>the</strong>y<br />

regard <strong>the</strong> future of <strong>the</strong>ir businesses.<br />

The index was calculated based <strong>on</strong> data<br />

ga<strong>the</strong>red from <strong>the</strong> main survey (2003)<br />

and after <strong>on</strong>e year from <strong>the</strong> follow-up survey<br />

(2004) about <strong>the</strong> expectati<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>the</strong><br />

entrepreneurs regarding specific issues<br />

related to <strong>the</strong> future of <strong>the</strong>ir firms.<br />

The index measures <strong>the</strong> future prospects<br />

of <strong>the</strong> entrepreneurs based <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

following factors: (i) employment; (ii)<br />

space of <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic unit; (iii) output;<br />

(iv)invested capital; (v) revenues; (vi)<br />

domestic sales; (vii) exports; and (viii)<br />

introducing new products[5].<br />

It was found that in Egypt, Morocco<br />

and Leban<strong>on</strong> most entrepreneurs<br />

-10-<br />

foresee no changes in <strong>the</strong>ir businesses.<br />

Entrepreneurs in Egypt had a more<br />

negative percepti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> future of<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir businesses in 2004 survey than<br />

in 2003[6]. The negative expectati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

were quite definite <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> number of<br />

<strong>the</strong> entrepreneurs who intend to leave<br />

<strong>the</strong> business or to decrease <strong>the</strong> number<br />

of workers, <strong>the</strong> value of assets,<br />

<strong>the</strong> output, <strong>the</strong> domestic sales and <strong>the</strong><br />

revenues. While in Leban<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> picture<br />

was completely different, with <strong>the</strong> number<br />

of entrepreneurs that expect <strong>the</strong><br />

growth of <strong>the</strong>ir firms larger than those<br />

that expect c<strong>on</strong>tracti<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>the</strong>ir activities.<br />

High expectati<strong>on</strong>s were particularly<br />

perceived in output (42% expected an<br />

increase in output) and domestic sales<br />

(54%). In Morocco <strong>the</strong> picture was<br />

similar to that of Leban<strong>on</strong>, where entrepreneurs<br />

that had good expectati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

about <strong>the</strong> future of <strong>the</strong>ir firms were<br />

larger than those with negative percepti<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

The expectati<strong>on</strong>s were higher in<br />

terms of future producti<strong>on</strong> (39%) and<br />

revenues (49%).<br />

Policy recommendati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

It is not difficult to generalize <strong>the</strong> policy<br />

recommendati<strong>on</strong>s that should be used<br />

to promote <strong>the</strong> MSE sector, as <strong>the</strong> basic<br />

needs of this sector are more or less<br />

<strong>the</strong> same in all <strong>the</strong> MPs. However some<br />

country specificity reflecting <strong>the</strong> special<br />

c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s under which this sector<br />

operates, have to be c<strong>on</strong>sidered. The<br />

recommendati<strong>on</strong>s should not <strong>on</strong>ly focus<br />

<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> policies that would enhance <strong>the</strong><br />

growth of <strong>the</strong> MSEs, but more importantly<br />

to improve <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir effectiveness<br />

and <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s under which <strong>the</strong>y<br />

operate. It should be noted that <strong>the</strong><br />

effectiveness of <strong>the</strong>se recommendati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

is c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>on</strong> pursuing macroec<strong>on</strong>o-


mic reforms pertaining to infrastructu-<br />

ral, fiscal, instituti<strong>on</strong>al, sectoral, and<br />

employment policies.<br />

√ It is important to differentiate between<br />

<strong>the</strong> micro and <strong>the</strong> small enterprises in<br />

designing <strong>the</strong> policies relevant to <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

growth. The two groups have different<br />

productivity schemes, different c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

different growth perspectives<br />

and different needs. Policies targeting<br />

Micro enterprises should focus <strong>on</strong> promoting<br />

<strong>the</strong> productivity and efficiency<br />

by providing technical assistance<br />

programs especially in cluster communities.<br />

Whereas policies directed<br />

towards small enterprises, need to be<br />

more diversified c<strong>on</strong>taining financial,<br />

technical and marketing supports and<br />

export promoti<strong>on</strong> programs.<br />

√ Policies should be directed to link<br />

this sector (specially <strong>the</strong> small <strong>on</strong>es)<br />

to larger firms. This sector could<br />

act as food industries, subc<strong>on</strong>tractors,<br />

service/maintenance providers<br />

of goods or services produced by <strong>the</strong><br />

larger companies. This sector can<br />

be c<strong>on</strong>sidered <strong>the</strong> missing middle<br />

that could link between larger firms.<br />

One suggesti<strong>on</strong> would be to give <strong>the</strong><br />

large firms those links with micro or<br />

small <strong>on</strong>es, special incentives or tax<br />

exempti<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

√ There is a need to provide an enabling<br />

business and instituti<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>ment.<br />

This includes <strong>the</strong> need to<br />

simplify <strong>the</strong> registrati<strong>on</strong> procedures<br />

and to design special tax schemes for<br />

this sector as incentives that would<br />

encourage it to operate formally. Most<br />

of <strong>the</strong> informal MSEs, have a tendency<br />

to avoid growth bey<strong>on</strong>d certain limits<br />

and/or prefer operating informally,<br />

-11-<br />

based <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> fear of having to deal<br />

with public administrati<strong>on</strong>s, taxes,<br />

etc. Also <strong>the</strong>re is a need to encourage<br />

MSEs to work in clusters so as<br />

to share <strong>the</strong> benefits of supporting<br />

counseling and services.<br />

√ As noted by most entrepreneurs in <strong>the</strong><br />

four surveys, access to official loans<br />

is a very difficult, if not an impossible,<br />

task. Loans could be granted to<br />

specialized activities/projects based<br />

<strong>on</strong> market needs, while reducing <strong>the</strong><br />

c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s and required guaranties.<br />

√ As reflected in <strong>the</strong> surveys, «<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

job training» is c<strong>on</strong>sidered <strong>the</strong> main<br />

(and sometimes <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly) source of<br />

training. In order to promote this<br />

sector, more formal training schemes<br />

should be organized. Public training<br />

centers are not enough; <strong>the</strong>re is a<br />

need to encourage NGOs and <strong>the</strong><br />

private sector to invest in <strong>the</strong> establishment<br />

of new modern specialized<br />

training centers and/or finance renovati<strong>on</strong><br />

and management of <strong>the</strong> existing<br />

public training centers.<br />

√ More specialized policies should be<br />

made to promote women entrepreneurs<br />

who are put at a disadvantaged<br />

positi<strong>on</strong>: <strong>the</strong>y are less educated, unskilled,<br />

untrained, <strong>the</strong>y suffer from low<br />

productivity, low earnings, <strong>the</strong>y have<br />

lower added-value; and have less<br />

access to assets and resources.<br />

√ The number of exporting MSEs is<br />

extremely low (if any). MSEs do not<br />

have <strong>the</strong> knowledge, experience or<br />

infrastructure required for exporting.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, training and counselling<br />

services <strong>on</strong> exporting, and <strong>the</strong> creati<strong>on</strong><br />

of specialized exporting enter-


prises capable of mediating between<br />

export markets and MSEs could be an<br />

effective way to promote an export<br />

culture am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> MSEs. MSEs with<br />

export potential should be informed<br />

about foreign markets as well as<br />

foreign enterprises to enhance <strong>the</strong><br />

possibility of an active cooperati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

2. The liberalisati<strong>on</strong>–employment<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship from <strong>the</strong> point of view<br />

of small enterprises<br />

The characteristics of small enterprises<br />

and employment, which are <strong>the</strong><br />

main part of <strong>the</strong> industrial network in<br />

MPs, allow us to better understand <strong>the</strong><br />

channels through which <strong>the</strong> expected<br />

benefits of an open ec<strong>on</strong>omy can be<br />

transmitted. However, <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>on</strong><br />

jobs should be defined in greater detail.<br />

That is to say, we should not <strong>on</strong>ly evaluate<br />

<strong>the</strong> global result, which has been<br />

modest, during <strong>the</strong> past ten years, but<br />

above all, <strong>the</strong> exact mechanisms that<br />

have led to this impact and which can<br />

lead to an improvement in potential<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequences.<br />

This is what ano<strong>the</strong>r study of <strong>Femise</strong><br />

has attempted to do[7], <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> basis<br />

of <strong>the</strong> annual survey of <strong>the</strong> Moroccan<br />

Ministry of Commerce and Industry<br />

covering <strong>the</strong> period from 1990-2002.<br />

The teams studied <strong>the</strong> process of creating<br />

and cutting jobs in <strong>the</strong> branches of<br />

<strong>the</strong> manufacturing industry, to obtain<br />

an exact understanding of <strong>the</strong> movement<br />

that is produced and that reflects<br />

<strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sequences of industrial adjustment.<br />

This does not allow an analysis<br />

at <strong>the</strong> sector level of <strong>the</strong> changes in net<br />

employment. The objective is to better<br />

understand <strong>the</strong> origins of employment<br />

reallocati<strong>on</strong> (size, sector and activity<br />

-12-<br />

of enterprises, its ability to export,<br />

etc.), its weight in industry and in<br />

categories of industries. Heterogeneous<br />

enterprises have been identified as an<br />

important explanati<strong>on</strong> for <strong>the</strong> job creati<strong>on</strong>/cutting<br />

waves, which, in this case,<br />

are not directly linked to specific sector<br />

shocks or fluctuati<strong>on</strong> cycles but to <strong>the</strong><br />

performance of firms. Through this analysis,<br />

it was possible to understand <strong>the</strong><br />

impact of an open ec<strong>on</strong>omy <strong>on</strong> employment<br />

in Morocco employment, which<br />

was symbolised by Morocco’s adherence<br />

to <strong>the</strong> WTO in l995 and <strong>the</strong> signing of an<br />

associati<strong>on</strong> agreement with <strong>the</strong> EU. The<br />

analysis was also c<strong>on</strong>ducted <strong>on</strong> Turkey<br />

with a similar objective.<br />

An in-depth study of <strong>the</strong> Moroccan case<br />

revealed that <strong>the</strong> rigidity of its labour<br />

market was a less important obstacle<br />

than claimed by previous studies and<br />

that manpower mobility was ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

high:<br />

√ In Morocco total net job creati<strong>on</strong><br />

was low (64,000 that is an average<br />

annual growth of 1.2% over that<br />

period), especially since 1998, in<br />

spite of great man-power mobility,<br />

dem<strong>on</strong>strated by <strong>the</strong> gross job creati<strong>on</strong><br />

figures (650,000) and gross<br />

job losses (586,000) and <strong>the</strong> feeble<br />

c<strong>on</strong>straints c<strong>on</strong>tained in legislati<strong>on</strong><br />

(especially for firing). This is <strong>the</strong> factor<br />

that is often blamed.<br />

√ Job creati<strong>on</strong> was quite regular. It rose<br />

to about 11.8% between 1990 and<br />

2002 (a 0.7 lower standard deviant)<br />

whereas job losses, were almost<br />

as high, (10.6) and more chaotic<br />

(1.9 standard deviant), which was<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sistent with <strong>the</strong> results obtained<br />

for o<strong>the</strong>r developing countries. This


can be explained by <strong>the</strong> fact that illustrated <strong>the</strong> impact of specialisati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

job cutting, more than job creati<strong>on</strong>, whose limits were beginning to produce<br />

is linked to <strong>the</strong> crisis. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> results that were prejudicial to job<br />

<strong>the</strong> slowdown of net job creati<strong>on</strong><br />

would be <strong>the</strong> reflecti<strong>on</strong> of a str<strong>on</strong>-<br />

creati<strong>on</strong>:<br />

ger eliminati<strong>on</strong> process ra<strong>the</strong>r than √ Sectors which absorbed most man-<br />

a drying up of <strong>the</strong> job creati<strong>on</strong> propower, especially unskilled labour,<br />

cess (Table X3).<br />

namely <strong>the</strong> textile and lea<strong>the</strong>r industries<br />

(46.7% of total manufacturing<br />

√ Job creati<strong>on</strong> was in 90% of cases <strong>the</strong> employment in 2002), chemistry and<br />

result of durable enterprises, which Parachemistry (19.4%) and food pro-<br />

was not <strong>the</strong> case for most o<strong>the</strong>r councessing industries (18.7%) have seen<br />

tries sampled in this analysis, but <strong>the</strong>ir c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to total employ-<br />

<strong>the</strong>se were also <strong>the</strong> enterprises that ment decline, a decade ago. The lat-<br />

cut <strong>the</strong> most jobs (57%), when <strong>the</strong>y ter al<strong>on</strong>e lost jobs in absolute terms<br />

reorganised <strong>the</strong>ir workforce (43% (Table X4). However, as <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>on</strong>d<br />

were <strong>the</strong> result of bankruptcy). These part of this report will dem<strong>on</strong>strate.<br />

job losses were very variable and This may also be <strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong> tex-<br />

fluctuated between 32.8% in 1999- tile and lea<strong>the</strong>r industry, as a result of<br />

2000 and 76% in 1993-1994.<br />

<strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> multi fibre agreement<br />

and <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong>se countries<br />

However, in additi<strong>on</strong> to <strong>the</strong> perfor- have not prepared for this situati<strong>on</strong><br />

mance of firms, <strong>the</strong> case of Morocco (decline in investments, etc.).<br />

Table X3: Net and Gross flows of workforce in <strong>the</strong> manufacturing industry in<br />

Morocco.<br />

Years<br />

Gross<br />

Net rate of Gross rate<br />

Rate of<br />

rate of<br />

creati<strong>on</strong> of creati<strong>on</strong><br />

reallocati<strong>on</strong><br />

destructi<strong>on</strong><br />

(NRC) (GRC)<br />

(RR)<br />

(GRD)<br />

1990-1991 3 12,3 9,3 21,6<br />

1991-1992 2,8 11,7 8,8 20,5<br />

1992-1993 2,2 12,3 10,1 22,3<br />

1993-1994 0,5 12,1 11,5 23,6<br />

1994-1995 1,7 11,7 10 21,6<br />

1995-1996 2,8 12 9,2 21,2<br />

1996-1997 2,9 10,9 8 18,9<br />

1997-1998 -2,4 10,5 12,9 23,4<br />

1998-1999 1,5 11,4 9,9 21,4<br />

1999-2000 -1,4 12,8 14,2 26,9<br />

2000-2001 0 12,9 12,9 25,8<br />

2001-2002 0,7 11,3 10,6 21,9<br />

Average 1,2 11,8 10,6 22,4<br />

S t a n d a r d<br />

Deviati<strong>on</strong><br />

1,8 0,7 1,9 2,6<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong>, from research n° FEM22-22<br />

-13


√ Electric and electr<strong>on</strong>ic industries were<br />

taking a more prominent positi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Though <strong>the</strong>y ranked <strong>on</strong>ly fifth in terms<br />

of total employment (5.6%), <strong>the</strong>y<br />

were dynamic in job creati<strong>on</strong> (22.7%<br />

between 1990 and 2002, of which<br />

-0.9% in 1990-1995 and 77.2% in<br />

1996 -2002). These figures were <strong>on</strong>ly<br />

surpassed by those of <strong>the</strong> textile and<br />

lea<strong>the</strong>r industries (81.9%). However,<br />

<strong>the</strong> role of this sector is still small<br />

and does not allow it to take over <strong>the</strong><br />

lea<strong>the</strong>r and textile sector in <strong>the</strong> short<br />

term (Table X5).<br />

√ In <strong>the</strong> textile and lea<strong>the</strong>r industry,<br />

which was <strong>the</strong> main c<strong>on</strong>tributor to<br />

manufacturing employment, it was<br />

<strong>the</strong> clothing industry that gave impetus<br />

to job creati<strong>on</strong>, while <strong>the</strong> textile<br />

industry lost steam. It was <strong>the</strong>refore,<br />

evident that <strong>the</strong> expected negative<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequences of <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> multi-<br />

-14-<br />

fibre agreements <strong>on</strong> Morocco were<br />

greater than an analysis by sector<br />

would have us believe. Moreover, this<br />

increasingly emphasised <strong>the</strong> inability<br />

of Morocco, unlike Turkey, as we shall<br />

see later, to develop an industry <strong>on</strong> its<br />

soil, which would enable it to capture<br />

part of <strong>the</strong> surplus (cloth can account<br />

for 60% of <strong>the</strong> price of an article of<br />

clothing), Ano<strong>the</strong>r factor was <strong>the</strong><br />

inability to c<strong>on</strong>trol costs and delivery<br />

dates which would, in <strong>the</strong> short term,<br />

greatly streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

faced by firms.<br />

√ Finally, gross job creati<strong>on</strong> came from<br />

enterprises, which had been established<br />

in <strong>the</strong> market for a l<strong>on</strong>g<br />

time (this was <strong>the</strong> case with 95% of<br />

<strong>the</strong> chemical-Parachemical industries,<br />

92% of <strong>the</strong> food processing industries<br />

and 92% of <strong>the</strong> mechanical and<br />

metallurgical industries). However,<br />

Table X4: Evoluti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of manufacturing employment by sector<br />

Years<br />

Food processing<br />

industries<br />

Textile and<br />

lea<strong>the</strong>r<br />

industries<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong>, from research n° FEM22-22<br />

Chemical and<br />

Parachemical<br />

industries<br />

Mechanical and<br />

metallurgical<br />

industries<br />

Electric and<br />

electr<strong>on</strong>ic<br />

industries<br />

1990 22,9 41,2 21,9 11,0 3,0 100<br />

1991 22,2 41,8 22,1 11,2 2,8 100<br />

1992 20,8 42,9 22,3 11,6 2,4 100<br />

1993 21,7 41,7 22,2 11,9 2,5 100<br />

1994 21,9 42,8 21,8 11,0 2,4 100<br />

1995 21,5 42,2 22,7 11,1 2,6 100<br />

1996 20,6 42,2 23,7 10,8 2,6 100<br />

1997 20,2 43,2 23,4 10,6 2,6 100<br />

1998 18,9 45,7 22,1 9,7 3,6 100<br />

1999 18,3 46,5 21,0 9,9 4,2 100<br />

2000 18,8 46,1 20,5 9,9 4,7 100<br />

2001 19,1 46,3 19,9 9,6 5,1 100<br />

2002 18,7 46,7 19,4 9,6 5,6 100<br />

Table X5: Sectoral c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> in net employment creati<strong>on</strong><br />

Years<br />

Food<br />

processing<br />

industries<br />

Textile and<br />

lea<strong>the</strong>r<br />

industries<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong>, from research n° FEM22-22<br />

Chemical and<br />

Parachemical<br />

industries<br />

Mechanical and<br />

metallurgical<br />

industries<br />

Electric and<br />

electr<strong>on</strong>ic<br />

industries<br />

1990-1995 8,1 50,8 29,9 12,1 -0,9 100<br />

1996-2002 -46,3 154,1 -58 -27,1 77,2 100<br />

Whole -8,3 81,9 3,4 0,3 22,7 100<br />

Total<br />

Total


<strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of newly established<br />

enterprises was greater than that of<br />

<strong>the</strong> less capitalistic textile and lea<strong>the</strong>r<br />

or electr<strong>on</strong>ics sectors. We shall again<br />

see <strong>the</strong> problem of access to financing<br />

for enterprises. Ano<strong>the</strong>r factor that<br />

should be taken into c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> is<br />

<strong>the</strong> big enterprises’ ability to adapt<br />

to <strong>the</strong> changed competitive situati<strong>on</strong><br />

at <strong>the</strong> internati<strong>on</strong>al level. Partnership<br />

agreements had not prepared <strong>the</strong>m<br />

for this eventuality, since it was reflected<br />

in outsourcing and an internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

divisi<strong>on</strong> of tasks but rarely in <strong>the</strong><br />

emergence of industries in <strong>the</strong> MPs,<br />

or sufficient increases in value to sell<br />

a product with a local brand name <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> European market.<br />

The Moroccan industry apparently, has<br />

still not initiated a transiti<strong>on</strong>al process<br />

towards a higher growth system, which<br />

would meet job c<strong>on</strong>straints. It is still<br />

dominated by branches that employ<br />

unskilled labour and produce little added<br />

value. The emergence of a more skilled<br />

labour intensive industry with high added<br />

value has proved difficult and <strong>the</strong> open<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omy has not been much help in this<br />

process. It can <strong>the</strong>refore be noted that:<br />

√ The employment structure hardly<br />

evolves; unskilled labour in 2002, as<br />

in 1990, accounts for 51% of total<br />

employment, jobs requiring skilled<br />

labour and training levels are still<br />

stagnate at around 39% and 10%<br />

respectively.<br />

√ Workers’ movements are mainly at<br />

<strong>the</strong> level of c<strong>on</strong>stant qualificati<strong>on</strong> in<br />

<strong>the</strong> clothing industry at <strong>the</strong> expense<br />

of <strong>the</strong> textile industry; <strong>the</strong> movement<br />

of workers from an industry that is<br />

not very capitalistic to ano<strong>the</strong>r indus-<br />

-15-<br />

try, which is capital intensive and<br />

skilled labour intensive is rare.<br />

√ Job creati<strong>on</strong> is not <strong>the</strong> prerogative<br />

of export-oriented enterprises[8].<br />

Those which are less export-oriented,<br />

or which <strong>on</strong>ly cater to <strong>the</strong><br />

local market, have similar results<br />

with regard to this aspect. However,<br />

<strong>the</strong> former have higher reallocati<strong>on</strong><br />

rates than <strong>the</strong> latter and <strong>the</strong>ir gross<br />

job loss rates are high and very<br />

much affected by crises, but <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

ability to create jobs is greater and<br />

has progressed between 1990 and<br />

2002. (-3.8 points for <strong>the</strong> latter)<br />

Above all, <strong>the</strong> development of gross<br />

rates between 1990/91 and 2001/02<br />

seem to indicate that export industries,<br />

as expected, have succeeded<br />

more in standing up to competiti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

since gross job loss rates have<br />

c<strong>on</strong>siderably fallen. C<strong>on</strong>versely,<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-export enterprises see <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

gross job loss rates increase with or<br />

without fluctuati<strong>on</strong>s. This, <strong>the</strong>refore,<br />

seems to c<strong>on</strong>firm <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>e hand,<br />

that <strong>the</strong> open ec<strong>on</strong>omy can produce<br />

a positive shock of competitiveness,<br />

which is reflected by improvement<br />

of gross and net job creati<strong>on</strong> possibilities.<br />

However, as predicted, it<br />

is accompanied by a negative effect<br />

<strong>on</strong> local enterprises (lower job creati<strong>on</strong><br />

rates and higher job loss rates)<br />

which, at <strong>the</strong> global level, (i) have<br />

a low net global impact, and (ii)<br />

threaten <strong>the</strong> dynamic process of<br />

job creati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> l<strong>on</strong>g term, which<br />

does not meet <strong>the</strong> needs of <strong>the</strong> MPs<br />

and will require acti<strong>on</strong>s to modify<br />

<strong>the</strong> present processes.<br />

√ Job reallocati<strong>on</strong> rates are estimated<br />

at 22.4% (taking into account job


creati<strong>on</strong> and job losses). This means<br />

that more than a fifth of <strong>the</strong> workforce<br />

is renewed every year.<br />

√ The heterogeneousness of firms inside<br />

this branch explains <strong>the</strong> volatility<br />

of job creati<strong>on</strong>. Enterprises can<br />

be divided into two groups: durable<br />

enterprises with great mobility, but<br />

which create almost as many jobs as<br />

<strong>the</strong>y lose and small enterprises that<br />

have been newly created and which<br />

have a large capacity for <strong>the</strong> absorpti<strong>on</strong><br />

of workers, but <strong>the</strong>y have a brief<br />

life–span and are rapidly changing.<br />

In Turkey[9], as in Morocco, short-term<br />

static effects <strong>on</strong> growth, related to <strong>the</strong><br />

reallocati<strong>on</strong> of resources in export-oriented<br />

sectors, which are exposed to internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

competiti<strong>on</strong>, should be limited<br />

-16-<br />

in general, and have a negative impact<br />

<strong>on</strong> employment. Dynamic effects, which<br />

bring a balanced l<strong>on</strong>g-term growth that<br />

is mainly due to technology transfers<br />

are supposed to dynamically activate<br />

employment, especially <strong>the</strong> employment<br />

of skilled workers and lead to productivity<br />

gains as is <strong>the</strong> case in <strong>the</strong> NICs in<br />

Asia.<br />

The Turkish export promoti<strong>on</strong> policy relied<br />

<strong>on</strong> an increase of subsidies accounting<br />

for 25% of commodity exports between<br />

1979 and 1990 (Table X7). Asian counties<br />

also resorted to such incentive measures,<br />

by linking <strong>the</strong> release of subsidies to <strong>the</strong><br />

export performances of enterprises. This<br />

policy was part of <strong>the</strong> more global liberalisati<strong>on</strong><br />

movement (deregulati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

labour market, financial liberalizati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

c<strong>on</strong>vertibility of capital accounts etc.).<br />

Table X6: Employment creati<strong>on</strong> and loss by <strong>the</strong> orientati<strong>on</strong> of activities of enterprises<br />

Exporting N<strong>on</strong> exporting<br />

% of exporting enterprises<br />

GRC GRD GRC GRD<br />

1990/1991 50,8 11,2 11 13,8 7,9<br />

1994/1995 50,9 13 11,2 10,5 8,9<br />

1999/2000 54,4 15,4 16,2 9,5 11,6<br />

2001/2002 56,1 14,1 6,9 10 14,1<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong>, from research n° FEM22-22<br />

Table X7: subsidies evoluti<strong>on</strong> for Turkish exports 1979-1990 (% of total exports)<br />

Direct<br />

subsidies<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong>, from research n° FEM22-22<br />

Export credits Import tax<br />

exempti<strong>on</strong><br />

Discount <strong>on</strong><br />

Total subsidies<br />

<strong>the</strong> VAT<br />

-1 -2 -3 -4 (=1+2+3+4)<br />

1979 11,0 9,9 0,3 0,0 21,2<br />

1980 5,6 14,9 4,2 - 26,7<br />

1981 9,1 13,0 3,3 - 27,4<br />

1982 15,1 10,8 3,6 - 31,5<br />

1983 17,4 10,5 5,6 - 35,9<br />

1984 17,3 5,9 2,0 2,0 27,2<br />

1985 10,0 2,0 5,1 2,0 19,1<br />

1986 9,9 4,8 8,6 2,6 25,9<br />

1987 8,6 2,9 6,7 4,3 22,5<br />

1988 7,6 4,8 6,6 4,3 22,5<br />

1989 5,5 8,8 7,7 5,9 27,9<br />

1990 4,4 9,2 7,7 6,2 27,5


The study revealed that in <strong>the</strong> case of<br />

Turkey, employment was:<br />

√ Positively related to producti<strong>on</strong> levels,<br />

but weak elasticity, (a 1% producti<strong>on</strong><br />

rise increased employment by 0.44)<br />

came from <strong>the</strong> development of <strong>the</strong><br />

informal sector, which has now reached<br />

about 50% of employment in <strong>the</strong><br />

period from 1988-2003,<br />

√ Negatively dependent <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> price of<br />

inputs, capital and investments made<br />

in <strong>the</strong> preceding period The adjustment<br />

of <strong>the</strong> producti<strong>on</strong> apparatus <strong>the</strong>refore<br />

weighed heavily <strong>on</strong> employment,<br />

√ The opening of <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy, evaluated<br />

up to <strong>the</strong> present, by import penetrati<strong>on</strong><br />

ratios, did not seem to have<br />

had a significant impact <strong>on</strong> jobs in <strong>the</strong><br />

manufacturing sector, even when an<br />

effect was detected, it was more likely<br />

to be a negative <strong>on</strong>e. This c<strong>on</strong>firmed<br />

<strong>the</strong> general results obtained for developing<br />

countries.<br />

Thus, in Turkey too, <strong>the</strong> expected possible<br />

effects of an open ec<strong>on</strong>omy <strong>on</strong><br />

employment have not yet been dem<strong>on</strong>strated.<br />

The extremely rapid development<br />

of informal employment however,<br />

makes <strong>the</strong> discouraging results relative.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, an analysis of specialisati<strong>on</strong><br />

reveals that Turkey is creating <strong>the</strong> necessary<br />

c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for greater and more<br />

stable growth in <strong>the</strong> l<strong>on</strong>g-term, which will<br />

create jobs for <strong>the</strong> most skilled workers.<br />

3. Determinants of behaviour: informality<br />

The preceding observati<strong>on</strong>s, which we<br />

have made <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> basis of several sur-<br />

-17-<br />

veys carried out by <strong>Femise</strong> <strong>on</strong> enterprises,<br />

statistical treatment of <strong>the</strong>se surveys<br />

and nati<strong>on</strong>al surveys <strong>on</strong> industries and<br />

analysis of employment growth, allow us<br />

to make <strong>the</strong> following c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s: <strong>the</strong><br />

feeble or even negative overall impact<br />

of an open ec<strong>on</strong>omy <strong>on</strong> employment is,<br />

to a great extent, due to <strong>the</strong> operati<strong>on</strong><br />

c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>the</strong>se industries, especially<br />

with regard to financing; (ii) adjustment<br />

performance can be substantially<br />

different between <strong>the</strong> various sectors<br />

of a given country and from <strong>on</strong>e MP<br />

to <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r (cf. Morocco and Turkey).<br />

This underscores <strong>the</strong> role played by <strong>the</strong><br />

expectati<strong>on</strong>s of local entrepreneurs; (iii)<br />

<strong>the</strong> incentives offered by public policies<br />

may lead firms to favour certain adjustment<br />

strategies over o<strong>the</strong>rs. This in<br />

turn, has a differentiated impact <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

increase of jobs that can be generated<br />

by opening competiti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Of <strong>the</strong> different performances analysed<br />

in <strong>the</strong> previous parts, <strong>the</strong> movement of<br />

enterprises to <strong>the</strong> informal sector has<br />

often been emphasised as having an<br />

important role in what is to be expected<br />

of an open ec<strong>on</strong>omy. This movement<br />

is often justified by <strong>the</strong> rigidity<br />

of <strong>the</strong> legal frameworks. However, it<br />

is difficult to distinguish between TWO<br />

different sectors, <strong>on</strong>e formal and <strong>the</strong><br />

o<strong>the</strong>r informal. As <strong>the</strong> next part of this<br />

report will show, enterprises “adjust”<br />

to a certain degree of informality with<br />

<strong>the</strong> development of <strong>the</strong> situati<strong>on</strong> and<br />

according to <strong>the</strong>ir percepti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

competitive envir<strong>on</strong>ment.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> next part of this report, based <strong>on</strong><br />

a <strong>Femise</strong> study which, in turn, was based<br />

<strong>on</strong> surveys[12], we show that <strong>the</strong> principle<br />

is that firms perceive <strong>the</strong> obstacles<br />

<strong>the</strong>y must face and <strong>the</strong>ir performance


according to <strong>the</strong> instituti<strong>on</strong>al, political<br />

and legal c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s in <strong>the</strong>ir countries.<br />

With <strong>the</strong> intensificati<strong>on</strong> of competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

and <strong>the</strong> hikes in oil prices we are faced<br />

with a “structure-management-performance”<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>, which means that firms<br />

will adapt <strong>the</strong>ir adjustment strategies<br />

to <strong>the</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text.. Performance is<br />

<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> result of acti<strong>on</strong>s or strategies<br />

which are part of <strong>the</strong> internal structural<br />

c<strong>on</strong>straints (technical characteristics of<br />

<strong>the</strong> firm, producti<strong>on</strong> and cost functi<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

organisati<strong>on</strong>al structure etc.), and external<br />

c<strong>on</strong>straints (sector characteristics,<br />

competitive positi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> firm etc.).<br />

On <strong>the</strong> basis of <strong>the</strong> survey c<strong>on</strong>ducted by<br />

<strong>the</strong> ROSES team, «governance» indicators<br />

and “competitive pressure” represent<br />

structural c<strong>on</strong>straints. There are<br />

also two gauges of firms’ performance,<br />

<strong>on</strong>e “syn<strong>the</strong>tic” or global (growth of<br />

enterprise etc.) and <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, which<br />

reflects <strong>the</strong>ir results <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

markets. The results of assessing <strong>the</strong><br />

impact of bel<strong>on</strong>ging to a given country<br />

<strong>on</strong> a firm’s performance and probity<br />

indicate that, if this impact is weak<br />

with regard to <strong>the</strong> overall performance<br />

of <strong>the</strong> firm, it is definitely weaker in<br />

its export capacity. Insofar as we have<br />

noted above, with <strong>the</strong> difference in job<br />

creati<strong>on</strong> potential between local firms<br />

and export-oriented firms (in <strong>the</strong> case<br />

of Morocco) <strong>the</strong> role of <strong>the</strong> local c<strong>on</strong>text<br />

has again been emphasised. However, in<br />

additi<strong>on</strong> to this simple result, far from<br />

being counter-intuitive, <strong>the</strong> interest of<br />

this study also lies in its identificati<strong>on</strong><br />

of entrepreneurs’ reacti<strong>on</strong> to corrupti<strong>on</strong><br />

and informal/formal arbitrati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong><br />

case of Maghreb. This enables us to pinpoint<br />

<strong>the</strong> role of enterprises in informal<br />

activity, when <strong>the</strong>y choose to resort to<br />

corrupti<strong>on</strong> and how <strong>the</strong>y see it.<br />

-18-<br />

Several determinants of informal activity<br />

have been identified by studies <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> effects of instituti<strong>on</strong>al changes related<br />

to <strong>the</strong> transiti<strong>on</strong> towards a market<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omy, particularly in <strong>the</strong> countries<br />

of <strong>the</strong> East. Thus, enterprises can (i)<br />

refrain from declaring all <strong>the</strong>ir revenues,<br />

if taxes are too high and rules too<br />

strict, (ii) practise <strong>the</strong>ir activity in <strong>the</strong><br />

informal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, if <strong>the</strong> extorti<strong>on</strong> to<br />

which <strong>the</strong>y are subjected is proporti<strong>on</strong>al<br />

to <strong>the</strong>ir producti<strong>on</strong> or, if <strong>the</strong> cost of<br />

this opportunity is low (resulting from<br />

a weak instituti<strong>on</strong>al framework, which<br />

involves, for instance <strong>the</strong> inability to<br />

respect property rights or a high degree<br />

of discreti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> part of government<br />

representatives when <strong>the</strong>y implement<br />

taxati<strong>on</strong> systems, etc.)<br />

As regards <strong>the</strong> inclinati<strong>on</strong> to engage in<br />

active corrupti<strong>on</strong>, which is defined as<br />

<strong>the</strong> enterprises’ offer to corrupt, which<br />

is <strong>the</strong> result of factors that can be divided<br />

into two categories: those which<br />

are related to <strong>the</strong> instituti<strong>on</strong>al set-up<br />

(breach of laws especially in an envir<strong>on</strong>ment<br />

that is not very competitive) and<br />

those which arise from <strong>the</strong> characteristics<br />

of <strong>the</strong> enterprises (enterprises that<br />

are not very competitive and are forced<br />

to break <strong>the</strong> rules of <strong>the</strong> game to survive,<br />

or according to <strong>the</strong> size and profitability<br />

of <strong>the</strong> firm, nature of its relati<strong>on</strong><br />

with <strong>the</strong> State etc).<br />

Several channels that affect <strong>the</strong> engagement<br />

in corrupti<strong>on</strong> by enterprises<br />

can be identified in <strong>the</strong> informal activities.<br />

First, with <strong>the</strong> growth of informal<br />

activity, <strong>the</strong> tax base is reduced which,<br />

<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>e hand, means a rise in taxes<br />

and drives people to find ways to avoid<br />

taxes (bribes etc.) and, <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, a<br />

fall in taxes, which are collected, means


a decline in public service which, in turn,<br />

leads to greater corrupti<strong>on</strong> and less<br />

protected property rights, (Johs<strong>on</strong> et al,<br />

1998). Sec<strong>on</strong>d, <strong>the</strong> degree of corrupti<strong>on</strong><br />

in a country is inversely proporti<strong>on</strong>al<br />

to <strong>the</strong> benefits that can be reaped by<br />

developing countries by respecting <strong>the</strong><br />

law. The more frequent <strong>the</strong> corrupti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

<strong>the</strong> greater <strong>the</strong> strategy aimed at eliminating<br />

<strong>the</strong> informal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. This, as<br />

a way to elude <strong>the</strong> authority of corrupt<br />

officials, will <strong>the</strong>refore be more probably<br />

reflected by an increase in corrupti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

In this case, according to Vostroknutova<br />

(2003), reducing corrupti<strong>on</strong> should be<br />

<strong>the</strong> first priority.<br />

Trade liberalisati<strong>on</strong>, c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> of new<br />

agreements and increased competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

usher in new opportunities, but <strong>the</strong>y also<br />

bring c<strong>on</strong>straints, mainly through <strong>the</strong><br />

change in laws, which oblige <strong>the</strong> firms to<br />

adapt and modify <strong>the</strong>ir activities.<br />

The survey c<strong>on</strong>ducted by <strong>the</strong> <strong>Femise</strong><br />

ROSES team <strong>on</strong> Algeria and Tunisia<br />

dem<strong>on</strong>strated that:<br />

√ The part of producti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cealed by <strong>the</strong><br />

enterprise would be (i) much higher<br />

than <strong>the</strong> sum of supplementary payments<br />

demanded (more than a third)<br />

(ii) corrupti<strong>on</strong> was seen as an important<br />

obstacle to its activity, (iii) this<br />

would enable it to reduce its tax levels.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, if <strong>the</strong> enterprise was not<br />

competitive, it could develop its informal<br />

activity, so as to reduce labour<br />

costs and evade complex procedures.<br />

√ The shortcomings of <strong>the</strong> legal system<br />

also explained <strong>the</strong> level of informal<br />

activity, insofar as <strong>the</strong> interest in<br />

declaring <strong>the</strong> activity was to protect<br />

it. Enterprises could <strong>the</strong>refore resort<br />

-19-<br />

to corrupti<strong>on</strong> to guarantee <strong>the</strong> protecti<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong>ir rights when <strong>the</strong> legal<br />

system was weak. If <strong>the</strong> authorities<br />

had little capacity to protect property<br />

or c<strong>on</strong>tractual rights, <strong>the</strong> opportunity<br />

cost of its activity in <strong>the</strong> informal ec<strong>on</strong>omy<br />

diminishes.<br />

√ Petty or day-to-day bribes, given or<br />

taken, <strong>on</strong> which <strong>the</strong> smooth running<br />

of firms’ activities relied, weighed<br />

more heavily <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> decisi<strong>on</strong> of enterprises<br />

to engage in informal activities<br />

than corrupti<strong>on</strong> designed to influence<br />

<strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tent of regulati<strong>on</strong>s and laws,<br />

which was <strong>the</strong> reflecti<strong>on</strong> of a more<br />

l<strong>on</strong>g-term strategy.<br />

√ The more important <strong>the</strong> informal activities<br />

were, <strong>the</strong> more firms were driven<br />

to engage in <strong>the</strong> different forms<br />

of corrupti<strong>on</strong>. However, it was a two<br />

edged weap<strong>on</strong>, as enterprises <strong>the</strong>n<br />

saw corrupti<strong>on</strong> as an obstacle to <strong>the</strong><br />

expansi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong>ir activities.<br />

√ Firms that found taxes to be c<strong>on</strong>straining<br />

are less sensitive to <strong>the</strong> problem<br />

of corrupti<strong>on</strong> since additi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

taxes in this sense are relatively less<br />

expensive.<br />

√ Firms believed that <strong>the</strong>y could get<br />

round <strong>the</strong> obstacle of laws that were<br />

too strict, not by weighing <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

c<strong>on</strong>tent of <strong>the</strong>se laws and regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

(State capture) but by <strong>the</strong>ir applicati<strong>on</strong><br />

(administrative corrupti<strong>on</strong>).<br />

√ The str<strong>on</strong>ger <strong>the</strong> market positi<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong> enterprise, <strong>the</strong> less likely it is that<br />

it would engage in corrupti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

These results emphasised that <strong>the</strong>re was<br />

a str<strong>on</strong>g positive correlati<strong>on</strong> between


informal activities and <strong>the</strong> percepti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

corrupti<strong>on</strong>; in whatever sense this word<br />

is used.<br />

They reinforced <strong>on</strong>e ano<strong>the</strong>r as has been<br />

observed in countries of <strong>the</strong> East, which<br />

were in a transiti<strong>on</strong>al stage. They also<br />

dem<strong>on</strong>strated that it was a matter of<br />

adjustment and optimisati<strong>on</strong> to be able<br />

to compete at <strong>the</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>al level.<br />

However, <strong>the</strong> practices of firms are, to<br />

a great extent dictated by <strong>the</strong> political<br />

c<strong>on</strong>text or <strong>the</strong>ir history. The political c<strong>on</strong>text,<br />

for instance, determines <strong>the</strong> inclinati<strong>on</strong><br />

of firms to accept to be subjected<br />

to corrupti<strong>on</strong>. If, in <strong>the</strong> political c<strong>on</strong>text,<br />

corrupti<strong>on</strong> is systematically denounced,<br />

<strong>the</strong> extent of corrupti<strong>on</strong>, in which <strong>the</strong><br />

administrati<strong>on</strong> and enterprises engage,<br />

will be reduced. However, with regard<br />

to <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>on</strong>d element, we can menti<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> existing or past relati<strong>on</strong>s between<br />

<strong>the</strong> enterprise and <strong>the</strong> State. Analysis<br />

shows that <strong>the</strong> closer <strong>the</strong> enterprise is to<br />

<strong>the</strong> authorities, <strong>the</strong> less it c<strong>on</strong>siders corrupti<strong>on</strong><br />

an obstacle to its development,<br />

probably because it can influence <strong>the</strong><br />

c<strong>on</strong>tent of law and regulati<strong>on</strong>s, without<br />

having to pay in return. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

hand, a public enterprise certainly has<br />

less inclinati<strong>on</strong> to capture <strong>the</strong> State,<br />

but as it is sometimes relatively more<br />

exposed to corrupti<strong>on</strong>, it may suffer.<br />

With regard to ec<strong>on</strong>omic policy recommendati<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

<strong>the</strong> results of this study<br />

emphasised that, in order to be effective<br />

in Algeria and Tunisia, a policy to combat<br />

<strong>the</strong> informal ec<strong>on</strong>omy must go handin–hand<br />

with a policy to reduce corrupti<strong>on</strong><br />

and improve <strong>the</strong> legal system,<br />

especially with regard to respect for c<strong>on</strong>tracts<br />

and property rights. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore,<br />

it was imperative to modify <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cept<br />

-20-<br />

that enterprises have of regulati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Regulati<strong>on</strong>s should not be c<strong>on</strong>sidered<br />

as obstacles, and this was particularly<br />

so with taxes. In additi<strong>on</strong>, to modificati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

of structures, <strong>the</strong>re should be an<br />

educati<strong>on</strong>al campaign, should first be<br />

c<strong>on</strong>ducted to explain to enterprises <strong>the</strong><br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequences of <strong>the</strong>ir choices.<br />

4. Behaviour Adjustments of enterprises<br />

and jobs<br />

The results of <strong>the</strong> open ec<strong>on</strong>omy in<br />

MPs first provided for in <strong>the</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

Agreements with <strong>the</strong> European Uni<strong>on</strong><br />

are, <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>e hand, dependent <strong>on</strong><br />

strategies adopted by firms, that is to<br />

say, <strong>the</strong> manner in which <strong>the</strong>y will face<br />

market developments and, and <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

o<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> development of <strong>the</strong>se different<br />

markets for different specialisati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

In this secti<strong>on</strong> we shall deal with<br />

<strong>the</strong> first point:<br />

An analysis of <strong>the</strong> liberalisati<strong>on</strong> – employment<br />

relati<strong>on</strong> should include three c<strong>on</strong>sequences<br />

that are expected as a result<br />

of increased trade:<br />

(i) Reallocati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> producti<strong>on</strong> factors<br />

in protected sectors to sectors<br />

exposed to foreign competiti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

which are supposed to offer higher<br />

return and salary rates;<br />

(ii) Reallocati<strong>on</strong> of productive resources<br />

in a given industry, from less to<br />

more efficient stakeholders. From<br />

this point of view <strong>the</strong> firms are heterogeneous;<br />

(iii) A change in <strong>the</strong> strategic opti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

chosen by firms in <strong>the</strong>ir adjustment.<br />

There are several opti<strong>on</strong>s, such as<br />

profit or salary margin squeezes,


more frequent recourse to unskilled<br />

or temporary labour, and search for<br />

improved productivity or quality of<br />

products, etc.<br />

A <strong>Femise</strong> study tried to define <strong>the</strong>se<br />

acti<strong>on</strong>s so as to evaluate <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> decisi<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>the</strong> existing industrial<br />

enterprises[10] <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> liberalisati<strong>on</strong>–<br />

employment relati<strong>on</strong>, with liberalisati<strong>on</strong><br />

referring mainly to <strong>the</strong> development<br />

of tariff and n<strong>on</strong>-tariff protecti<strong>on</strong>. The<br />

study identified <strong>the</strong> sectors, in which<br />

<strong>the</strong> modificati<strong>on</strong>s of intensive competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

were more significant <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> basis<br />

of a ratio of import penetrati<strong>on</strong>[11].<br />

The industries affected were <strong>the</strong> lea<strong>the</strong>r,<br />

furniture and its accessories, rubber<br />

and o<strong>the</strong>r manufacturing industries<br />

in Turkey, as well as textiles, manufacture<br />

of metal objects, machines and<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir material, radio sets and equip-<br />

-21-<br />

ment, televisi<strong>on</strong>s and communicati<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

<strong>the</strong> car industry and o<strong>the</strong>r transport<br />

materials.<br />

It seems that in <strong>the</strong> case of Turkey,<br />

and as dem<strong>on</strong>strated in <strong>the</strong>ory, <strong>the</strong><br />

industries facing increasing competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

saw <strong>the</strong>ir producti<strong>on</strong> fall. (Figures 1,<br />

2, 3, 4), while total industrial producti<strong>on</strong><br />

increased. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> graphs<br />

for industry reveal a disc<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong><br />

between producti<strong>on</strong> developments and<br />

employment, which is not corroborated<br />

by sector dynamics and, as a result,<br />

can be attributed to <strong>the</strong> specificities<br />

of <strong>the</strong> envir<strong>on</strong>ment and acti<strong>on</strong>s of<br />

firms. In Morocco, this disc<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong><br />

between total industrial producti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

producti<strong>on</strong> by industry and <strong>the</strong> producti<strong>on</strong>–employment<br />

relati<strong>on</strong> in industries,<br />

which increasingly faced competiti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

was clearly less marked and <strong>the</strong> adjust-<br />

Figure 1: Evoluti<strong>on</strong> of producti<strong>on</strong> and employment for <strong>the</strong> whole industry<br />

Figure 2: Evoluti<strong>on</strong> of producti<strong>on</strong> and employment for <strong>the</strong> firms bel<strong>on</strong>ging to <strong>the</strong><br />

most open to foreign competiti<strong>on</strong> sectors<br />

Turkey<br />

Producti<strong>on</strong><br />

Morocco<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong>, from research n° FEM22-22<br />

Morocco<br />

Turkey Producti<strong>on</strong> Ttl employmt<br />

Producti<strong>on</strong> Ttl employmt<br />

Ttl employmt Producti<strong>on</strong> Ttl employmt


ment was achieved by a fall in <strong>the</strong> that seem to have led to <strong>the</strong>se results, a<br />

apparent productivity of work.<br />

competitive locati<strong>on</strong> in a given country.<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r <strong>Femise</strong> studies have dealt with<br />

Increased competiti<strong>on</strong> can indeed lead<br />

firms to adopt different types of adjust-<br />

this aspect (see below).<br />

ment measures: <strong>the</strong>y can play with <strong>the</strong> To identify <strong>the</strong> strategy adopted in each<br />

selling price (reducing input prices, country, <strong>the</strong> study <strong>the</strong>n assessed <strong>the</strong><br />

salaries and accepting profit mar- impact of liberalisati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> employgin<br />

squeezes while increasing technical ment using an ec<strong>on</strong>ometric fixed effect<br />

efficiency), or <strong>the</strong>y may improve <strong>the</strong> approach to a sample group for <strong>the</strong><br />

quality of <strong>the</strong>ir products and/or <strong>the</strong> 1993-2002 period or <strong>the</strong> 1995-2001<br />

quantity sold. The differences in <strong>the</strong> period in Morocco (when <strong>the</strong> various<br />

developments of acti<strong>on</strong>s by each indus- elements of employment were introtry<br />

and total industries, which appear duced in <strong>the</strong> analysis) and 1985-1990<br />

between Morocco and Turkey, probably for Turkey. 4 digit import ratios were<br />

arise from <strong>the</strong> strategic choices taken used al<strong>on</strong>g with <strong>the</strong> ad valorem ave-<br />

to adapt to <strong>the</strong> modificati<strong>on</strong>s required rage of customs duties, according to<br />

by competiti<strong>on</strong>: Turkey succeeded in <strong>the</strong> available data. 7 sub- samples of<br />

maintaining apparent and overall pro- firms were identified, according to<br />

ductivity through investment efforts, <strong>the</strong>ir characteristics: those which were<br />

while Morocco opted for a price policy most exposed to internati<strong>on</strong>al compe-<br />

with a cutback in profits and producti<strong>on</strong> titi<strong>on</strong>, those which, over a period of<br />

costs. However, <strong>the</strong>re are o<strong>the</strong>r factors time, had seen <strong>the</strong>ir producti<strong>on</strong> inclined<br />

Figure 3: Evoluti<strong>on</strong> of apparent productivity for <strong>the</strong> whole industry<br />

Turkey App. Prodty Morocco<br />

App. Prodty<br />

Figure 4: Evoluti<strong>on</strong> of apparent productivity for enterprises of <strong>the</strong> sectors most open<br />

to foreign competitive<br />

App. Prodty Turkey Morocco<br />

App. Prodty<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong>, from research n° FEM22-22<br />

-22


to increase or fall, those which expor-<br />

ted more than 25% of <strong>the</strong>ir producti<strong>on</strong><br />

and those which exported less than<br />

25% of <strong>the</strong>ir producti<strong>on</strong>, enterprises<br />

which had a workforce of more than a<br />

100 employees in Morocco and 150 in<br />

Turkey, and those which had a smaller<br />

workforce. These estimates revealed<br />

that:<br />

√ The liberalisati<strong>on</strong>-employment relati<strong>on</strong><br />

was globally weak and negative.<br />

This c<strong>on</strong>firmed <strong>the</strong> results obtained by<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r teams working <strong>on</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r countries.<br />

Thus, in <strong>the</strong> case of Morocco, a<br />

ten point tariff reducti<strong>on</strong> resulted in<br />

a 1% fall of employment in industry,<br />

but it could reach 3%, if <strong>the</strong> enterprise<br />

was big or export-oriented. This<br />

effect was still more marginal in <strong>the</strong><br />

case of Turkey, since a 10% rise in<br />

import ratio was reflected by 0.3 job<br />

loss, and <strong>on</strong>ly certain types of firms<br />

were affected (big firms or firms with<br />

falling producti<strong>on</strong>).<br />

√ A crucial element in <strong>the</strong> liberalisati<strong>on</strong>-employment<br />

relati<strong>on</strong> in Morocco<br />

was that of <strong>the</strong> exchange rate policy<br />

with falling employment (mainly<br />

temporary). It could go up to 7%<br />

in reacti<strong>on</strong> to a 10% real appreciati<strong>on</strong><br />

in exchange rates. Firms, which<br />

were most vulnerable, were obviously<br />

those which were export-oriented.<br />

However, this effect was not systematically<br />

negative in Turkey. This<br />

can be explained by <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>siderable<br />

volume of imported inputs in producti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

whose costs were reduced when<br />

<strong>the</strong> exchange rates were appreciated.<br />

This increased <strong>the</strong> productivity<br />

of commodities and employment.<br />

(+2.5%+3.5% for a 10% appreciati<strong>on</strong><br />

in exchange rates).<br />

-23-<br />

√ Adjustments of <strong>the</strong> workforce have<br />

been made, to meet <strong>the</strong> changed<br />

c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of competiti<strong>on</strong> or m<strong>on</strong>ey<br />

value. In Morocco, this was achieved<br />

through more frequent recourse to<br />

temporary employment, and particularly<br />

unskilled labour. This movement<br />

was not obvious in industry as a<br />

whole, but in certain industries, which<br />

have rec<strong>on</strong>sidered <strong>the</strong> management<br />

opti<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>the</strong>ir job structures.<br />

√ In <strong>the</strong> case of Turkey, <strong>the</strong>re were two<br />

elements that have weighed heavily<br />

<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> liberalisati<strong>on</strong>–employment<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>. The first was positive, <strong>the</strong><br />

margin achieved, when it was positive,<br />

could enable a 0.8% to a 1.3%<br />

increase in employment for a 10%<br />

appreciati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> exchange rate.<br />

The sec<strong>on</strong>d was negative: a 1% overall<br />

improvement of productivity could<br />

lead to a 2.8% decline in employment.<br />

It would be worth knowing if<br />

such a development of productivity<br />

was possible. It was <strong>the</strong> result of capital<br />

intensiveness which, if increased<br />

by 10%, would reduce employment<br />

by 1%, even if <strong>the</strong> investment, in<br />

itself, improved employment (+0.4%<br />

to +1.2% for a 10 % appreciati<strong>on</strong>).<br />

To c<strong>on</strong>clude this part <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> behaviour<br />

of firms in <strong>the</strong>ir day-to-day operati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

and <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong> open ec<strong>on</strong>omy <strong>on</strong><br />

employment, we should emphasise <strong>the</strong><br />

following:<br />

√ The liberalisati<strong>on</strong> policy, which almost<br />

all <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean countries have<br />

adopted, has changed <strong>the</strong> competitive<br />

c<strong>on</strong>text which local firms will have<br />

to face. The open ec<strong>on</strong>omy policy,<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r it is multilateral in origin<br />

(WTO) or regi<strong>on</strong>al (<strong>the</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong>


Agreements) <strong>the</strong>refore not <strong>on</strong>ly has a<br />

macro-ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>tent, it also has<br />

a micro-ec<strong>on</strong>omic impact. In reacti<strong>on</strong><br />

to changes in <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>text of competiti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

firms have resorted to different<br />

strategies, which arose from <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

need to develop <strong>the</strong>ir activities (or at<br />

least to survive) and from <strong>the</strong> possibilities<br />

<strong>the</strong>y have through <strong>the</strong>ir local<br />

c<strong>on</strong>text.<br />

√ These activities, here as elsewhere,<br />

were reflected by acti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> usual<br />

levers, mainly investments, margins<br />

and jobs. From this point of view,<br />

<strong>the</strong> choices made by Mediterranean<br />

countries, with regard to employment<br />

and investment, were not in line with<br />

micro-ec<strong>on</strong>omic needs. (cf. for instance<br />

<strong>the</strong> textile-clothing industry in<br />

Morocco).<br />

√ As regards <strong>the</strong> public acti<strong>on</strong>s to be<br />

taken at this level, various surveys<br />

<strong>on</strong> different but c<strong>on</strong>nected and complementary<br />

subjects, which were<br />

made <strong>on</strong> several countries (Algeria,<br />

Egypt, Leban<strong>on</strong>, Morocco, Tunisia and<br />

Turkey), have c<strong>on</strong>firmed <strong>the</strong> priorities<br />

already emphasised by <strong>Femise</strong>. These<br />

priorities were: improving c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

to make firms competitive, especially<br />

with regard to basic services in<br />

financing and communicati<strong>on</strong>s, which<br />

would allow enterprises access to<br />

financial resources and enable <strong>the</strong>m<br />

to export at <strong>the</strong> lowest cost, providing<br />

training to develop <strong>the</strong> necessary<br />

skills to upgrade all types of industries,<br />

streamlining administrative<br />

procedures that are still complicated<br />

and opaque, so that enterprises could<br />

perceive positive c<strong>on</strong>sequences for<br />

<strong>the</strong> greatest “formalisati<strong>on</strong>” of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

activity.<br />

-24-<br />

Finally, ano<strong>the</strong>r important point was<br />

that <strong>the</strong> behaviour of firms was dictated<br />

by <strong>the</strong> general developments in <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

sector, internati<strong>on</strong>al dynamics and evoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong> laws regulating this sector.<br />

This aspect is dealt with in <strong>the</strong> following<br />

part, first by highlighting <strong>the</strong> specific<br />

aspects of Mediterranean countries in<br />

<strong>the</strong> course of <strong>the</strong>ir industrial development,<br />

<strong>the</strong>n by examining in detail <strong>the</strong><br />

exemplary dynamics of <strong>the</strong> textile-clothing<br />

sector, and by pointing out future<br />

opportunities, mainly in <strong>the</strong> services<br />

sector, and in particular, those which<br />

were referred to above.<br />

II. Adjustment of sector specialisati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

to modify dynamics<br />

1. A specific industrial path<br />

An analysis of a country’s specialisati<strong>on</strong><br />

cannot be ignored in any study <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

effects of <strong>the</strong> liberalisati<strong>on</strong> strategy,<br />

whatever its origin, (changes in <strong>the</strong><br />

provisi<strong>on</strong>s of an agreement, admissi<strong>on</strong><br />

of a new member to <strong>the</strong> WTO etc.). In<br />

this first part, we should obtain a better<br />

understanding of <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>going industrialisati<strong>on</strong><br />

process in <strong>the</strong> MPs to make a<br />

first assessment of <strong>the</strong>ir ability to c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>t<br />

<strong>the</strong> shock of competiti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

At <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> 1960s, all <strong>the</strong> MPs had a<br />

comparative advantage in primary commodities.<br />

However, <strong>the</strong> structural adjustment<br />

policies, devaluati<strong>on</strong> of exchange<br />

rates and <strong>the</strong> liberalisati<strong>on</strong> policy of <strong>the</strong><br />

1980s led <strong>the</strong>m to develop new comparative<br />

advantages, modify <strong>the</strong>ir specialisati<strong>on</strong><br />

and reallocate <strong>the</strong> factors of producti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>omic development is in fact<br />

a process of improving productivity that<br />

is based <strong>on</strong> a sound investment dynamic<br />

process and growth[13].


History has shown us that this process<br />

is invariably associated with structural<br />

change in producti<strong>on</strong> and employment,<br />

from agriculture towards industry, and<br />

<strong>the</strong>n gradually between different branches<br />

of <strong>the</strong> manufacturing industry.<br />

Though it may not be linear, this<br />

development is systematically oriented<br />

towards a prol<strong>on</strong>gati<strong>on</strong> of output<br />

diversi<strong>on</strong>. The interpretati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong> principle underlying <strong>the</strong> growing<br />

divisi<strong>on</strong> of labour, as an evoluti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong> industrial structure to increasingly<br />

intensive branches of intermediary<br />

goods, enables us to c<strong>on</strong>struct a typology<br />

of three groups of branches in<br />

<strong>the</strong> manufacturing industry. The formalisati<strong>on</strong><br />

of industrial development<br />

and gradual movement of <strong>the</strong> centre<br />

of gravity from simple labour-intensive<br />

producti<strong>on</strong> (IPS-L) towards simple<br />

capital intensive producti<strong>on</strong> (IPS–C)<br />

<strong>the</strong>n towards intermediary goods (IPC)<br />

- intensive producti<strong>on</strong>, defines <strong>the</strong><br />

standard path of industrialisati<strong>on</strong>. This<br />

path has been successfully tested in<br />

<strong>the</strong> l<strong>on</strong>g dynamic processes of <strong>the</strong> big<br />

industrialised countries. An empirical<br />

examinati<strong>on</strong> reveals that <strong>the</strong> l<strong>on</strong>g processes<br />

of sector change were geared<br />

towards <strong>the</strong> same general tendencies.<br />

They fell within <strong>the</strong>se limits, which were<br />

identifiable and <strong>the</strong>y were c<strong>on</strong>vergent.<br />

They <strong>the</strong>refore defined a sequence,<br />

which generally characterized <strong>the</strong> evoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong> industrial structure. From<br />

England at <strong>the</strong> beginning of <strong>the</strong> 19th<br />

century to South Korea and Taiwan in<br />

<strong>the</strong> last third of <strong>the</strong> twentieth century,<br />

all <strong>the</strong> industrialisati<strong>on</strong> processes have<br />

followed this path of sector sequence.<br />

However, nati<strong>on</strong>al rhythms were not<br />

identical. The later industrializati<strong>on</strong> was<br />

in coming, <strong>the</strong> steeper <strong>the</strong> slopes and<br />

<strong>the</strong> more rapid <strong>the</strong> structural change.<br />

-25-<br />

The c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>tati<strong>on</strong> of structural change<br />

in industries in <strong>the</strong> MPs with this standard<br />

sequence of industrializati<strong>on</strong> since<br />

<strong>the</strong> early 1960s generally indicated an<br />

evoluti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> meaning of development<br />

in <strong>the</strong> wr<strong>on</strong>g directi<strong>on</strong>. The lowering<br />

of <strong>the</strong> IPS-L may seem to have<br />

c<strong>on</strong>formed to <strong>the</strong> historical sequence,<br />

but <strong>the</strong> main particularity of <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

industrial dynamic process was <strong>the</strong><br />

stagnati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> IPC at a low level.<br />

This movement to <strong>the</strong> rear of <strong>the</strong><br />

industrialisati<strong>on</strong> process was particularly<br />

obvious in Turkey, Morocco and,<br />

to a lesser extent, Jordan. The most<br />

modern IPC industries remained marginal<br />

or were relatively decreasing,<br />

whereas <strong>the</strong> support industries for an<br />

industrial takeoff (IPS-L) still represented<br />

a c<strong>on</strong>siderable part of manufacturing<br />

producti<strong>on</strong>. The dynamic process<br />

of structural change seemed relatively<br />

better orientated, if weak, in Egypt. As<br />

Israel was a case apart, Turkey represented<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly real difference to<br />

<strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>al trend. Its industrializati<strong>on</strong><br />

sequence was close to those of South<br />

Korea and Taiwan, but with a 25 year<br />

gap between <strong>the</strong>m.<br />

A comparis<strong>on</strong> with o<strong>the</strong>r developing<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>s emphasised <strong>the</strong> countertendency<br />

nature of developments<br />

in <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean regi<strong>on</strong>. The<br />

industrialisati<strong>on</strong> process in <strong>the</strong> NIC2<br />

(Thailand, Malaysia, Ind<strong>on</strong>esia and<br />

<strong>the</strong> Philippines) and also in China<br />

followed <strong>the</strong> same historical path of<br />

industrialisati<strong>on</strong>, but with a time gap<br />

between <strong>the</strong>m. Industrial growth may<br />

have been slower in South West Asia,<br />

but <strong>the</strong> same sequence of structural<br />

change, at a slower pace, could be<br />

observed.


This age-old orientati<strong>on</strong> of industrialisa- <strong>the</strong> speedy industrial transiti<strong>on</strong> of MPs,<br />

ti<strong>on</strong> was also observed in Latin America, which seemed relevant but <strong>the</strong> directi<strong>on</strong><br />

in spite of <strong>the</strong> slow pace of industrial<br />

modernizati<strong>on</strong> and <strong>the</strong> “lost decades”.<br />

to be taken.<br />

The MPs were <strong>the</strong>refore, <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly coun- 2. The impact of industrial strateter-tendency<br />

case in this sample. The gies <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> liberalisati<strong>on</strong>-employ-<br />

hypo<strong>the</strong>sis of a late start seemed less<br />

relevant than that of structural inertia.<br />

ment relati<strong>on</strong><br />

In <strong>the</strong> early 1970s, <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean The hypo<strong>the</strong>sis, often put forward by<br />

countries had more advanced industrial <strong>Femise</strong>, was that this inertia was partly<br />

structures than <strong>the</strong> NIC2: Since <strong>the</strong>n, due to <strong>the</strong> desire to preserve employ-<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean has been chament, by favouring relatively labourracterised<br />

by a stable hierarchy in <strong>the</strong> intensive industries. This objective might<br />

three groups of industries. The fact that seem perfectly rati<strong>on</strong>al and might well be<br />

<strong>the</strong> IPC was not adopted led us to c<strong>on</strong>- tenable in a closed ec<strong>on</strong>omy. However,<br />

clude that <strong>the</strong>re was a poor divisi<strong>on</strong> of it was not <strong>on</strong>ly difficult to uphold in <strong>the</strong><br />

labour and insufficient building of new l<strong>on</strong>g term, but it was also inc<strong>on</strong>sistent<br />

industrial skills in <strong>the</strong> past four deca- with <strong>the</strong> present general movement<br />

des. In fact, it was not <strong>the</strong> questi<strong>on</strong> of towards liberalisati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> MPs. On <strong>the</strong><br />

c<strong>on</strong>trary, in this c<strong>on</strong>-<br />

Table X8: Employment coefficients by principal industrial<br />

sectors[15]<br />

text, present speciali-<br />

Sectors 1985-1995 1995-2001 1985-2001<br />

sati<strong>on</strong>s seemed coun-<br />

FPI 0,5 1,0 0,5<br />

terproductive in terms<br />

Ind<strong>on</strong>esia<br />

CPCI<br />

EEI<br />

0,6<br />

0,5<br />

1,2<br />

1,0<br />

0,8<br />

0,5<br />

of jobs, as a compa-<br />

MMI 0,4 1,5 0,7<br />

rative analysis made<br />

TCI 0,5 1,9 1,0<br />

in a <strong>Femise</strong> study<br />

Total<br />

FPI<br />

0,5<br />

0,7<br />

1,3<br />

1,1<br />

0,7<br />

0,8<br />

showed[14]. This<br />

CPCI 0,7 1,1 0,7<br />

study was c<strong>on</strong>cerned<br />

Malaysia EEI<br />

MMI<br />

0,5<br />

0,5<br />

0,9<br />

1,1<br />

0,5<br />

0,6<br />

with <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sequen-<br />

TCI 0,4 1,1 0,4<br />

ces of <strong>the</strong> choice of<br />

Total 0,6 1,0 0,6<br />

specialisati<strong>on</strong>s in <strong>the</strong><br />

FPI<br />

CPCI<br />

0,6<br />

0,5<br />

1,1<br />

1,1<br />

0,7<br />

0,6<br />

areas of growth and<br />

EEI 0,6 1,3 0,7<br />

jobs for five countries<br />

Morocco MMI<br />

TCI<br />

Total<br />

0,4<br />

0,6<br />

0,5<br />

1,2<br />

1,3<br />

1,1<br />

0,5<br />

0,7<br />

0,6<br />

(Morocco,<br />

Turkey,<br />

Tunisia,<br />

Malaysia,<br />

FPI 1,0 0,9 0,9<br />

Ind<strong>on</strong>esia) in <strong>the</strong><br />

CPCI<br />

EEI<br />

1,4<br />

1,4<br />

1,2<br />

1,9<br />

1,6<br />

2,7<br />

period from 1985-<br />

Tunisia MMI 1,0 0,9 0,9<br />

2001 (which was<br />

TCI 0,8 1,3 1,1<br />

divided into two sub-<br />

Total<br />

FPI<br />

1,1<br />

0,4<br />

1,2<br />

1,0<br />

1,3<br />

0,4<br />

periods 1985-1995<br />

CPCI 0,3 1,1 0,3<br />

and 1995-2001). It<br />

Turkey EEI<br />

MMI<br />

0,3<br />

0,3<br />

1,2<br />

1,1<br />

0,4<br />

0,3<br />

compared <strong>the</strong> results<br />

TCI 0,4 1,2 0,4<br />

in terms of growth<br />

Total 0,3 1,1 0,4<br />

and jobs in <strong>the</strong> sec-<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong>, study FEM22-22, ONUDI <strong>2005</strong>, author’s calculati<strong>on</strong> tors of <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy,<br />

-26-


so as to establish a typology of sectors<br />

that best addressed <strong>the</strong> difficulties met<br />

in MPs.<br />

Generally speaking, <strong>the</strong> 1995-2001<br />

period was more favourable for <strong>the</strong><br />

creati<strong>on</strong> of jobs in <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean<br />

countries and Asia. This proved that<br />

this was not due to <strong>the</strong> effect of “trade<br />

integrati<strong>on</strong> with <strong>the</strong> EU”. Job coefficients<br />

in Morocco, Tunisia and Turkey were<br />

more similar in <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>on</strong>d period, while<br />

<strong>the</strong>y were more different in <strong>the</strong> first.<br />

Tunisia led <strong>the</strong> group with coefficients<br />

that were higher than 1 and were slightly<br />

improving (Table x8). The sectors,<br />

which generated most jobs were <strong>the</strong><br />

same in <strong>the</strong> three MPs (<strong>the</strong> electric and<br />

electr<strong>on</strong>ics industry (EEI), <strong>the</strong> textileclothing<br />

industry (TCI) and <strong>the</strong> chemical<br />

and Parachemical industry (CPCI)). This<br />

meant that <strong>the</strong>y had similar specialisati<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

which were different from those<br />

found in Asian countries, while, in <strong>the</strong><br />

Asian countries specialisati<strong>on</strong>s differed<br />

from <strong>on</strong>e country to <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r. In<br />

Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, <strong>the</strong> sectors, which created<br />

most jobs, were <strong>the</strong> mechanical, metallurgy<br />

and machinery industries (MMI)<br />

and <strong>the</strong> food processing industry (FPI).<br />

However <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s of each sector<br />

to net job creati<strong>on</strong> and added value,<br />

seen in perspective, emphasised that<br />

(table X9):<br />

√ The strategies of Asian countries<br />

were to develop relatively more technology<br />

and skilled labour–intensive<br />

sectors. This enabled <strong>the</strong>m to capture<br />

part of <strong>the</strong> internati<strong>on</strong>al market,<br />

while keeping sectors that had<br />

a big capacity to absorb manpower<br />

(Rizwanul, 2003). Ind<strong>on</strong>esia overcame<br />

<strong>the</strong> crisis, which had dealt a<br />

-27-<br />

severe blow to <strong>the</strong> TCI and <strong>the</strong> MMI,<br />

which c<strong>on</strong>tinued to play an important<br />

part in job creati<strong>on</strong>. It preferred to<br />

build sectors, such as <strong>the</strong> electr<strong>on</strong>ics<br />

and chemical sectors, which<br />

are playing an increasing role as an<br />

impetus to growth and job creati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Malaysia, <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, opted<br />

for a much more rapid restructuring.<br />

It supported electric and electr<strong>on</strong>ics<br />

industries, which now have a key role<br />

in <strong>the</strong> absorpti<strong>on</strong> of employment and<br />

<strong>the</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> of wealth (80% of job<br />

creati<strong>on</strong>).<br />

√ Tunisia had adopted a strategy that<br />

was more similar to that of <strong>the</strong><br />

Asian countries. It preserved <strong>the</strong><br />

textile-clothing sector, in which it had<br />

a comparative advantage and which<br />

had created many jobs, but it also<br />

reoriented its specialisati<strong>on</strong> towards<br />

<strong>the</strong> FPI and <strong>the</strong> EEI, while disengaging<br />

itself from <strong>the</strong> CPCI. Similarly,<br />

Turkey relied <strong>on</strong> and streng<strong>the</strong>ned its<br />

comparative advantages in <strong>the</strong> TCI<br />

sector, which c<strong>on</strong>tinued to play an<br />

important part in job creati<strong>on</strong>. It also<br />

tried to diversify its industry, particularly<br />

<strong>the</strong> CPCI and <strong>the</strong> MMI.<br />

√ There was a gap in <strong>the</strong> MPs, especially<br />

in Morocco, between employment<br />

systems and <strong>the</strong> sectors, which gave<br />

impetus to growth. The 1985-1995<br />

specialisati<strong>on</strong> structure dem<strong>on</strong>strated<br />

that <strong>the</strong> TCI created jobs, while <strong>the</strong><br />

CPCI, <strong>the</strong> FPI and, to a lesser extent,<br />

<strong>the</strong> TCI created wealth. The changes<br />

resulting from <strong>the</strong> Barcel<strong>on</strong>a process<br />

were reflected in a diversificati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong> sectors that promoted growth,<br />

such as <strong>the</strong> EEI and <strong>the</strong> MMI. The<br />

capacity of those industries to absorb<br />

manpower is <strong>the</strong> weakest.


Ano<strong>the</strong>r study c<strong>on</strong>ducted by <strong>Femise</strong>[16]<br />

analysing <strong>the</strong> transformati<strong>on</strong> of manufactured<br />

exports c<strong>on</strong>firmed <strong>the</strong>se results.<br />

The comparis<strong>on</strong> between <strong>the</strong> evoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong> manufactured exports of MPs and<br />

those of <strong>the</strong> emerging countries, mainly<br />

<strong>the</strong> two generati<strong>on</strong>s of NIC and China,<br />

revealed that exports had played a<br />

very modest role in <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean.<br />

The differential between <strong>the</strong>ir export<br />

dynamism and <strong>the</strong> average of developing<br />

countries increased, even though<br />

<strong>the</strong> associati<strong>on</strong> agreements offered <strong>the</strong><br />

MPs privileged access to <strong>the</strong> European<br />

Table X9: Sectoral c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s*<br />

Ind<strong>on</strong>esia<br />

Malaysia<br />

Morocco<br />

Tunisia<br />

Turkey<br />

-28-<br />

market. This quantitative approach was<br />

completed by an analysis of <strong>the</strong> «quality»<br />

of exports from MPs, in a dynamic<br />

and comparative perspective, which<br />

relied <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> of a syn<strong>the</strong>tic<br />

indicator (IRX). Export Catch up<br />

Indicator. The export catch up indicator<br />

syn<strong>the</strong>sised <strong>the</strong> level of sophisticati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

exports from each country and, in every<br />

period, marked that level <strong>on</strong> an internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

scale, which moved from <strong>the</strong> least<br />

to <strong>the</strong> most performing. The calculati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

of this indicator were not based <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

characteristics of <strong>the</strong> product, but ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

Employment creati<strong>on</strong> Value Added<br />

1985-1995 1995-2001 1985-2001 1985-1995 1995-2001 1985-2001<br />

FPI 15% (-68%) 12% 17% (-8%) 20%<br />

CPCI 31% 50% 34% 29% (-15%) 33%<br />

EEI 5% (-32%) 4% 7% (-5%) 7%<br />

MMI 11% 28% 13% 27% (-30%) 26%<br />

TCI 37% 22% 37% 20% (-42%) 13%<br />

Total 100% 100% 100% 100% (-100%) 100%<br />

FPI 5% 18% 6% 8% (-5%) 7%<br />

CPCI 33% (-12%) 32% 35% (-47%) 30%<br />

EEI 37% 82% 42% 34% 100% 44%<br />

MMI 18% (-27%) 16% 18% (-35%) 15%<br />

TCI 7% (-61%) 5% 5% (-14%) 4%<br />

Total 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100%<br />

FPI 31% 15% 27% 39% 34% 39%<br />

CPCI 17% 17% 17% 30% 19% 30%<br />

EEI 1% 11% 3% 2% 24% 3%<br />

MMI 6% 16% 8% 10% 23% 11%<br />

TCI 45% 42% 44% 19% (-100%) 16%<br />

Total 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100%<br />

FPI 15% 2% 12% 16% 33% 17%<br />

CPCI 23% 17% 22% 36% 24% 36%<br />

EEI 4% 25% 9% 4% 26% 6%<br />

MMI 13% (-100%) 9% 10% (-100%) 9%<br />

TCI 45% 57% 49% 33% 17% 33%<br />

Total 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100%<br />

FPI 4% 1% 14% 5% 13%<br />

CPCI 13% 22% 19% 41% 43% 41%<br />

EEI 6% 4% 5% 6% (-100%) 5%<br />

MMI 0% 17% 11% 21% 24% 22%<br />

TCI 80% 53% 64% 18% 28% 19%<br />

Total 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100%<br />

* : Positive c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s to <strong>the</strong> absolute variati<strong>on</strong> in employment and deflated VA. For informati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong><br />

negative c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s are denoted in italic and paren<strong>the</strong>sis.<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong> research FEM22-22


<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> exporters of <strong>the</strong>se products. They<br />

were inspired by a method which was<br />

first proposed by C. H. Kwan (2002) in<br />

ano<strong>the</strong>r c<strong>on</strong>text. The export catch up<br />

indicator enabled us to measure <strong>the</strong><br />

gap between <strong>the</strong> exportati<strong>on</strong> structure<br />

of a developing country and that of a<br />

country, which had <strong>the</strong> most advanced<br />

exportati<strong>on</strong> structure and how to narrow<br />

this gap. This is <strong>the</strong> countries’ export<br />

catch up dynamics. The applicati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

this method to <strong>the</strong> structure of world<br />

trade since <strong>the</strong> mid 1960s again emphasised<br />

<strong>the</strong> particular positi<strong>on</strong> of Morocco<br />

and Tunisia. While Israel and Turkey had<br />

seen an evoluti<strong>on</strong> similar to that of <strong>the</strong><br />

newly industrialised countries2, Tunisia<br />

and Morocco which had <strong>the</strong> same catch<br />

up indicator as <strong>the</strong> NIC2 up to <strong>the</strong><br />

early 1970s, witnessed different developments<br />

.Their export catch up indictor<br />

fluctuated, but remained very low.<br />

This comparative approach was completed<br />

by a more fine-tuned analysis of<br />

diversificati<strong>on</strong> niches (level 4 of SITC<br />

that is a thousand jobs) between 1994<br />

and 2003. When we set aside exports<br />

related to exploitati<strong>on</strong> of natural resources<br />

and textiles-clothing, niches became<br />

almost n<strong>on</strong>-existent in Jordan and Syria,<br />

and rare in Egypt. A stable number of<br />

about ten could be found in Morocco and<br />

Tunisia, and about twenty in Turkey. With<br />

regard to demand, <strong>the</strong>se niches were<br />

found in markets which were not very<br />

dynamic. In <strong>the</strong>se segments competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

between <strong>the</strong> Maghreb and Mashrek<br />

countries was weak, but it was str<strong>on</strong>g<br />

between <strong>the</strong> MPs and Turkey. In <strong>the</strong><br />

Maghreb, <strong>the</strong>se niches were mostly for<br />

inter–company trade toward Europe.<br />

In this market <strong>the</strong> MPs were more<br />

in competiti<strong>on</strong> with East and Central<br />

European Countries than with Asia and<br />

-29-<br />

China. This c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>tati<strong>on</strong> and <strong>the</strong> predominance<br />

of inter-firm trade suggested<br />

that <strong>the</strong> diversificati<strong>on</strong> of MPs’ exports<br />

was halted by <strong>the</strong> irrupti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> CEEC,<br />

which attracted massive European FDI in<br />

<strong>the</strong> 1990s.<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r indicators c<strong>on</strong>firmed <strong>the</strong>se trends.<br />

The analysis of investment efforts,<br />

added value, employment and apparent<br />

productivity of labour revealed that <strong>the</strong><br />

specializati<strong>on</strong> resulting from liberalising<br />

and upgrading <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy did not put<br />

Morocco <strong>on</strong> a growth path, which would<br />

be c<strong>on</strong>sistent with its unemployment<br />

problems[17]. Graver still, <strong>the</strong>re was<br />

a process of deskilling labour, which<br />

explained <strong>the</strong> growing difficulties faced<br />

by graduates in finding jobs.<br />

With regard to forms of sector adjustment,<br />

it should be noted that, in <strong>the</strong> case<br />

of Morocco, <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>going process of specialisati<strong>on</strong><br />

in <strong>the</strong> electric and electr<strong>on</strong>ics<br />

industries did not lead to an up-market<br />

positi<strong>on</strong>. Employment and investment<br />

had greatly progressed at <strong>the</strong> beginning<br />

of <strong>the</strong> period, but <strong>the</strong> apparent productivity<br />

of labour and real salaries had<br />

c<strong>on</strong>siderably declined as of 1995. This<br />

was due to <strong>the</strong> fact that Morocco was<br />

mainly a sub-c<strong>on</strong>tractor in this sector.<br />

In Tunisia, <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, employment<br />

had increased fivefold between<br />

1993 and 2001 for this very same sector.<br />

However, real salaries fell sharply and<br />

<strong>the</strong> progress of investment and added<br />

value was slow.<br />

The situati<strong>on</strong> in Turkey was totally different<br />

as this sector generated a substantial<br />

and rapidly rising added value and<br />

offered <strong>the</strong> highest remunerati<strong>on</strong> levels.<br />

Malaysia was in a similar positi<strong>on</strong>: progress<br />

in employment, added value and


investment, fall in salaries and increased<br />

labour productivity. The same applied to<br />

Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, which trailed a little behind,<br />

but took <strong>the</strong> same course.<br />

As regards <strong>the</strong> textile-clothing industry,<br />

<strong>the</strong> important investments made<br />

in 1993 to 1996, did not reactivate <strong>the</strong><br />

hoped for growth or added value, while<br />

salaries remained at <strong>the</strong>ir former levels.<br />

An up-market positi<strong>on</strong> would <strong>the</strong>refore<br />

be difficult to achieve especially in view<br />

of <strong>the</strong> disrupti<strong>on</strong> caused by <strong>the</strong> end of<br />

<strong>the</strong> multi-fibre accords. For Tunisia this<br />

meant ei<strong>the</strong>r a c<strong>on</strong>siderable fall in salaries<br />

which did not promote investment<br />

or an improvement in apparent labour<br />

productivity, which was increasingly deskilled.<br />

Turkey <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, found <strong>the</strong><br />

way to achieve an up-market positi<strong>on</strong>:<br />

investment at a swift pace, which has<br />

not slowed down, and has even quickened<br />

in view of <strong>the</strong> possible adverse<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequences of <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> multifibre<br />

accord. Added value producti<strong>on</strong><br />

and <strong>the</strong> apparent productivity of labour<br />

increased throughout <strong>the</strong> period and<br />

jobs were created for relatively more<br />

skilled workers. Ind<strong>on</strong>esia presented a<br />

similar situati<strong>on</strong> with investments that<br />

did not lag, stable salaries and apparent<br />

productivity levels and more jobs.<br />

In Morocco, investment mainly served<br />

<strong>the</strong> chemical and food processing industries.<br />

The former was a key sector of <strong>the</strong><br />

Moroccan ec<strong>on</strong>omy and maintained its<br />

job creati<strong>on</strong> capacity and salary levels<br />

in spite of trends towards a fall in <strong>the</strong><br />

apparent productivity of labour that followed<br />

<strong>the</strong> drop in added value, which,<br />

at <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> period, was joined by<br />

a fall in salaries. Tunisia, because of<br />

<strong>the</strong> gradual exhausti<strong>on</strong> of its natural<br />

-30-<br />

resources, mainly petroleum, saw <strong>the</strong><br />

importance of this sector decline (fall in<br />

salaries, added value, and investments,<br />

employment was maintained but apparent<br />

labour productivity was reduced by<br />

50%).<br />

In this area, Turkey relied again <strong>on</strong> its<br />

investments. This explained <strong>the</strong> good<br />

results in terms of added value and<br />

labour productivity, but it was not a very<br />

dynamic sector in terms of employment.<br />

Ind<strong>on</strong>esia adopted <strong>the</strong> same type of<br />

strategy: investment fuelled by productivity<br />

and added value gains, but here<br />

<strong>the</strong> sector created employment.<br />

The food processing sector also suffered<br />

from a lack of dynamism as of <strong>the</strong><br />

sec<strong>on</strong>d half of <strong>the</strong> 1990s. Employment<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tinued to increase slowly, but added<br />

value fell, dragging productivity with<br />

it. In this sector in Turkey and Tunisia,<br />

str<strong>on</strong>g investments maintained productivity<br />

levels. Salaries greatly increased<br />

in Tunisia and were am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> highest<br />

in Turkey.<br />

One of <strong>the</strong> few sectors in which investment<br />

efforts remained important at <strong>the</strong><br />

end of <strong>the</strong> period was <strong>the</strong> mechanical and<br />

metallurgical industries. In spite of this,<br />

added value c<strong>on</strong>tinued to decline, while<br />

employment and salaries increased. This<br />

proved that <strong>the</strong> investments were not<br />

sufficiently developed. The performances<br />

of Turkey or Malaysia were much better,<br />

because investment did not falter over<br />

all <strong>the</strong> period and added value increased<br />

at <strong>the</strong> same pace, while employment<br />

remained stable.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> that arises now is to find<br />

<strong>the</strong> result, in terms of employment, of<br />

<strong>the</strong>se different industrial strategies in<br />

<strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>text of trade liberalisati<strong>on</strong>. From


this point of view, <strong>the</strong> job c<strong>on</strong>tent of<br />

trade c<strong>on</strong>firmed <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> Asian<br />

countries, which we have c<strong>on</strong>sidered,<br />

had a completely different strategy than<br />

that adopted by <strong>the</strong> MPs.<br />

The former based <strong>the</strong>ir ec<strong>on</strong>omic development<br />

<strong>on</strong> heavy and often diversified<br />

industrialisati<strong>on</strong>. They thus protected<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir capacity to absorb unskilled manpower<br />

and increased <strong>the</strong>ir capacity to<br />

absorb more skilled workers. The strategy<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Asian countries c<strong>on</strong>sisted of<br />

<strong>the</strong> following elements:<br />

(i) On <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>e hand, <strong>the</strong> protecti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

emerging ec<strong>on</strong>omies, which were<br />

intended to create opportunities to<br />

gain an up-market positi<strong>on</strong>, such as<br />

developing <strong>the</strong> electric and electr<strong>on</strong>ics<br />

industries. This renewed <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

comparative advantages and gave<br />

<strong>the</strong>m a positi<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> more dynamic<br />

sectors at <strong>the</strong> internati<strong>on</strong>al level. The<br />

human and financial requirements<br />

for <strong>the</strong> reorientati<strong>on</strong> of specialisati<strong>on</strong><br />

were met, thanks to <strong>the</strong> firm<br />

commitment of <strong>the</strong> State, which also<br />

targeted <strong>the</strong> sectors that should be<br />

streng<strong>the</strong>ned and expanded;<br />

(ii) On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, <strong>the</strong> restructuring<br />

of traditi<strong>on</strong>al sectors by making<br />

investments, this, at times, could be<br />

very substantial. These investments<br />

often resulted in an up-market positi<strong>on</strong>,<br />

while maintaining job creati<strong>on</strong><br />

level.<br />

This industrial strategy preserved social<br />

cohesi<strong>on</strong> and created opportunities for<br />

growth, so that <strong>the</strong> country could more<br />

easily absorb <strong>the</strong> structural adjustments<br />

related to internal macroec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>straints<br />

and internati<strong>on</strong>al competiti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

-31-<br />

Thus, Ind<strong>on</strong>esia preserved jobs for uns-<br />

killed labour in <strong>the</strong> textile and clothing<br />

industries, while developing <strong>the</strong> more<br />

capital and skilled labour-intensive chemical<br />

and electr<strong>on</strong>ics sectors. Malaysia,<br />

where <strong>the</strong> restructuring of industry was<br />

more advanced, followed <strong>the</strong> same path<br />

and now it can focus <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> sophisticated<br />

electric and electr<strong>on</strong>ics industries,<br />

which have become sufficiently dynamic<br />

to create employment. The main c<strong>on</strong>cern<br />

of <strong>the</strong> interventi<strong>on</strong> policies of <strong>the</strong>se<br />

countries was to make <strong>the</strong> skills acquired<br />

in <strong>the</strong> educati<strong>on</strong>al system adequate<br />

to <strong>the</strong> industries’ requirements for qualified<br />

workers.<br />

As regards <strong>the</strong> MPs, <strong>the</strong>re has been no<br />

improvement in trade-related jobs in<br />

<strong>the</strong> two sub-periods, with <strong>the</strong> excepti<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong> textile-clothing industries. Turkey<br />

was in a relatively better positi<strong>on</strong> because<br />

of its investment behaviour.<br />

The great difference between <strong>the</strong> performances<br />

of <strong>the</strong> MPs and those of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Asian countries was partly due to<br />

<strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> two groups of countries<br />

had different c<strong>on</strong>cepts of <strong>the</strong> role<br />

of industry in growth and, for both of<br />

<strong>the</strong>m; <strong>the</strong> questi<strong>on</strong> of jobs was presented<br />

in different terms. The proof lay in<br />

<strong>the</strong> development of <strong>the</strong> tertiary sector,<br />

which followed and accompanied <strong>the</strong><br />

development of industry, and influenced<br />

its activities (banking, c<strong>on</strong>sultancy to<br />

enterprises etc.) in Asian countries. In<br />

<strong>the</strong> MPs, <strong>the</strong> influence of <strong>the</strong> tertiary<br />

sector hardly reflected <strong>the</strong> stage of <strong>the</strong><br />

country’s industrialisati<strong>on</strong>. It was relatively<br />

disc<strong>on</strong>nected and required a soluti<strong>on</strong><br />

to <strong>the</strong> supply of unskilled labour.<br />

This positi<strong>on</strong> did not seem optimal even<br />

though it met short-term needs and<br />

assured <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tinuity of social order,


it eliminated <strong>the</strong> l<strong>on</strong>g-term capacity to<br />

absorb jobs and greatly affected <strong>the</strong><br />

quality of manpower.<br />

The grave crises, which Turkey encountered,<br />

may have promoted <strong>the</strong>se restructuring<br />

efforts by lowering opportunity<br />

costs, and giving it a big leap forward in<br />

<strong>the</strong> transiti<strong>on</strong>al process. For <strong>the</strong> MPs, <strong>the</strong><br />

risk faced by <strong>the</strong> rest of <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy,<br />

because of <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> multi-fibre<br />

accord with its induced investments,<br />

could oblige <strong>the</strong>m to accelerate <strong>the</strong><br />

pace of levelling <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy and find<br />

a strategy to develop new comparative<br />

advantages, since <strong>the</strong>y had a stock of<br />

highly qualified manpower <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>e<br />

hand, and could rise to an up-market<br />

positi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, if <strong>the</strong>y did not<br />

c<strong>on</strong>fine <strong>the</strong>mselves to sub-c<strong>on</strong>tracting,<br />

which would not allow <strong>the</strong>m to capture a<br />

big part of <strong>the</strong> income. The experience<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Asian countries or Turkey showed<br />

that a country could change its positi<strong>on</strong> in<br />

<strong>the</strong> internati<strong>on</strong>al market, provided that it<br />

adopted firm industrial policies and <strong>the</strong>re<br />

was a str<strong>on</strong>g State commitment.<br />

This commitment might be to act as an<br />

investor, but <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> questi<strong>on</strong> of maintaining<br />

<strong>the</strong> necessary equilibrium would<br />

arise. Then too, <strong>the</strong>re was <strong>the</strong> questi<strong>on</strong><br />

of breaking off with <strong>the</strong> former system,<br />

which we should admit, has proved its<br />

limitati<strong>on</strong>s. It could also move to acti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

in <strong>the</strong> firms’ behaviour, as we have<br />

seen in <strong>the</strong> first part. The stakeholders’<br />

movement should be accompanied by a<br />

process that facilitated <strong>the</strong>ir day-to-day<br />

operati<strong>on</strong>s, so that <strong>the</strong>y could adopt<br />

strategies that were c<strong>on</strong>sistent with<br />

nati<strong>on</strong>al objectives. As we have seen<br />

earlier, <strong>the</strong> dynamics of <strong>the</strong> textile clothing<br />

sector was an excellent example of<br />

this point of view.<br />

-32-<br />

3. The textile, revealing industrial<br />

sector dynamic<br />

The textile-clothing industry sector has<br />

been <strong>the</strong> engine of development in many<br />

countries and c<strong>on</strong>tinues to be of importance<br />

for developing countries. Within<br />

<strong>the</strong> EU, <strong>the</strong> share in value-added of textile-clothing<br />

(TC) in <strong>the</strong> manufacturing<br />

sector increased to 4% and absorbs 7% of<br />

employment. Italy, The United Kingdom,<br />

France, Germany and Spain produce three<br />

quarters of <strong>the</strong> EU textiles-clothing. A total<br />

of 200 billi<strong>on</strong> Euros divided am<strong>on</strong>g 177<br />

000 enterprises employing more than 2<br />

milli<strong>on</strong> individuals[18]. The largest exporters<br />

of textiles are China, Italy, Germany,<br />

The Republic of Korea, Taipei, France,<br />

Belgium, Japan and The United Kingdom,<br />

while in <strong>the</strong> clothing industry, China, Italy,<br />

Germany, France, Turkey, Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, The<br />

Republic of Korea and Thailand dominate.<br />

But, in <strong>the</strong> case of MPs, <strong>the</strong> stakes are<br />

high, firstly because of <strong>the</strong> historic role<br />

played by <strong>the</strong> sector in <strong>the</strong> industrializati<strong>on</strong><br />

of ec<strong>on</strong>omies, <strong>the</strong>n by its weight today<br />

in <strong>the</strong>ir industries, in <strong>the</strong>ir exchanges<br />

and above all in employment, and finally<br />

because at <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> shock of a major<br />

opening, that is <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> multi-fiber<br />

agreement. In two years time, this will<br />

entail transiti<strong>on</strong>al measures to be taken by<br />

<strong>the</strong> EU and <strong>the</strong> United States when <strong>the</strong>y<br />

will have realized <strong>the</strong> potential quantitative<br />

impact. This sector is very symptomatic of<br />

<strong>the</strong> role that could be played by different<br />

industrial strategies, ei<strong>the</strong>r by comparing<br />

MPs to Asian countries or MPs with <strong>on</strong>e<br />

ano<strong>the</strong>r.<br />

Expansi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> textile network<br />

Morocco and Tunisia were very open<br />

countries before <strong>the</strong>ir independence


whose nati<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omy largely depen-<br />

ded <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> importati<strong>on</strong> of European pro-<br />

ducts in TC sector. The achievement of<br />

independence coincided with <strong>the</strong> implementati<strong>on</strong><br />

of alternative plans regarding<br />

exports that boosted investment. 41%<br />

of approved investments in Morocco<br />

were directed to textile-clothing in 1960.<br />

However, <strong>the</strong>se plans rapidly indicated<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir limits and new measures were<br />

taken to promote <strong>the</strong> role of exports<br />

in growth. In 1972, Tunisia promulgated<br />

a law that established <strong>the</strong> status of<br />

exporting enterprise and provided fiscal<br />

advantages, while firms were encouraged<br />

to produce for <strong>the</strong> internal market<br />

which remained protected. Morocco<br />

followed <strong>the</strong> same course. Its structural<br />

adjustment programme of 1983 and<br />

promulgati<strong>on</strong> of investment and exportati<strong>on</strong><br />

codes fur<strong>the</strong>red <strong>the</strong> development<br />

of exchanges.<br />

The expansi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> textile-clothing<br />

industry in <strong>the</strong>se countries benefited<br />

<strong>the</strong> movement of European delocalizati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

which originally stood at around<br />

30% of investments accomplished in<br />

Morocco after 1987 and <strong>the</strong> signing of<br />

<strong>the</strong> EU-Tunisia <strong>partnership</strong> agreement<br />

in 1976. This industry created 40% of<br />

new jobs in <strong>the</strong> Tunisian manufacturing<br />

sector between 1972 and 1981 and 48%<br />

in Morocco between 1980 and 2000.<br />

It accounts for 40% of manufactured<br />

exports in Tunisia in 1980, higher than<br />

<strong>the</strong> rate in Morocco or Turkey.<br />

The structure of <strong>the</strong> TC industry in <strong>the</strong><br />

three Maghreb countries varies greatly.<br />

In Algeria, at <strong>the</strong> outset of <strong>the</strong> 1980s,<br />

<strong>the</strong> sector represented 30% of total<br />

industrial employment. Prior to privatizati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

which began in <strong>the</strong> 1990s,<br />

<strong>the</strong> textile sector was dominated by<br />

-33-<br />

public enterprises while private companies<br />

occupied a prep<strong>on</strong>derant place in<br />

<strong>the</strong> garment sector. These two sectors<br />

fell into crisis as <strong>the</strong>y were incapable of<br />

c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>ting <strong>the</strong> competitiveness brought<br />

about by privatizati<strong>on</strong>s. In 2001, <strong>the</strong><br />

producti<strong>on</strong> of textiles stabilized by 25%<br />

of its 1990 level and clothing at around<br />

40%. Employment declined markedly<br />

until 2000. In <strong>the</strong> first stage of privatizati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

Algerian retailers demanded<br />

more and more foreign products, but<br />

this trend was reversed and domestic<br />

producti<strong>on</strong> augmented recently. In<br />

2002, <strong>the</strong> sector accounted for 4.4% of<br />

industrial producti<strong>on</strong> (hydrocarb<strong>on</strong>s not<br />

included) whereas <strong>the</strong> private TC sector<br />

represented 9.9% of <strong>the</strong> value of producti<strong>on</strong><br />

in 2003.<br />

Egypt followed a very different course.<br />

The industry developed thanks to <strong>the</strong><br />

support of Bank Misr at <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong><br />

War, with Misr Spinning and Weaving<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sidered <strong>the</strong> largest enterprise in <strong>the</strong><br />

Middle East, accounting for 25 000<br />

employees. Since 1945, <strong>the</strong> TC industry<br />

occupies a dominant positi<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong><br />

Egypt ec<strong>on</strong>omy reaching 42.4% enterprises<br />

and 37% of jobs in <strong>the</strong> manufacturing<br />

sector. Since <strong>the</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>alizati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

of 1960-1962 when <strong>on</strong>ly establishments<br />

of less than 200 employees remained<br />

private, <strong>the</strong> public sector dominated <strong>the</strong><br />

textile while <strong>the</strong> private sector c<strong>on</strong>trolled<br />

<strong>the</strong> clothing industry (75% of exports).<br />

The textile industry is also very old in<br />

Turkey. Largely dependent <strong>on</strong> imports<br />

as l<strong>on</strong>g as it had not regained its customs<br />

aut<strong>on</strong>omy, <strong>the</strong> country has, within<br />

<strong>the</strong> framework of <strong>the</strong> first five-year plan<br />

and Soviet aid, entrusted Sumerbank<br />

with <strong>the</strong> development of <strong>the</strong> TC sector.<br />

However, here <strong>the</strong> private sector was


above all active in <strong>the</strong> producti<strong>on</strong> of yarn<br />

and fabric (50% to 60%).<br />

Textile activity developed significantly<br />

after <strong>the</strong> Sec<strong>on</strong>d World War, benefiting<br />

from <strong>the</strong> cott<strong>on</strong> boom as a result of<br />

<strong>the</strong> war in Korea, as well as incentives<br />

for investment in <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>text of import<br />

substituti<strong>on</strong> policies and protecti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong> domestic market. It was <strong>on</strong>ly thanks<br />

to <strong>the</strong> open trade policy and promoti<strong>on</strong><br />

of exports that <strong>the</strong> clothing sector took<br />

off and its export performance reached a<br />

peak at <strong>the</strong> end of 1980s. In <strong>the</strong> 1990s,<br />

<strong>the</strong> privileged relati<strong>on</strong>s between Turkey<br />

and Germany and <strong>the</strong> perspective of a<br />

customs uni<strong>on</strong> with <strong>the</strong> EU promoted<br />

garment exports and supported and<br />

encouraged c<strong>on</strong>siderable efforts toward<br />

investment and <strong>the</strong> modernizati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

enterprises.<br />

The TC is an essential comp<strong>on</strong>ent of<br />

industrial exportati<strong>on</strong> in Jordan, Leban<strong>on</strong>,<br />

Morocco, Syria and Turkey. Given <strong>the</strong><br />

inability of most of <strong>the</strong>se countries to<br />

create a network <strong>on</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>al territory,<br />

it is equally an important positi<strong>on</strong> for<br />

imports.<br />

The TC c<strong>on</strong>tinues to be <strong>the</strong> main comp<strong>on</strong>ent<br />

of <strong>the</strong> manufacturing sector and<br />

<strong>the</strong> major employer in Egypt, Morocco,<br />

Tunisia and Turkey. In Morocco, it c<strong>on</strong>tributed<br />

to creating 60% new manufacturing<br />

jobs since 1986 against more<br />

than 30% industrial jobs in Tunisia. It is<br />

a str<strong>on</strong>gly feminized and informal occupati<strong>on</strong><br />

and <strong>the</strong> figures <strong>on</strong> employment in<br />

this sector are not reliable. Moreover,<br />

professi<strong>on</strong>als in Turkey estimate that<br />

employment in <strong>the</strong> sector is five times<br />

higher than that which appears in <strong>the</strong><br />

statistics. Ano<strong>the</strong>r difficulty, it is difficult<br />

to evaluate producti<strong>on</strong> in as much as<br />

-34-<br />

certain enterprises[19], in this activity,<br />

often some of <strong>the</strong> largest in <strong>the</strong> country<br />

that generate c<strong>on</strong>siderable exports, are<br />

in close proximity with many SME.<br />

Major importance at <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

and social levels<br />

In Morocco as in Tunisia, <strong>the</strong> clothing sector<br />

occupies a central role in manufactured<br />

exports since <strong>the</strong> 1980s. C<strong>on</strong>cerning<br />

Tunisia, since 1996, textiles represent<br />

more than half of exports in terms of<br />

manufactured products and in 2001,<br />

textiles, footwear and lea<strong>the</strong>r accounted<br />

for 48.5% of <strong>the</strong> value of total exports<br />

(this figure dropped to 42% in 2002).<br />

Morocco is in a similar situati<strong>on</strong>: TC<br />

exports rose to 23% of <strong>the</strong> total value of<br />

manufactured exports in 1996 and 33%<br />

in 2001[20]. Regarding Algeria, <strong>the</strong> percentage<br />

is lower[21].<br />

In <strong>the</strong> three Maghreb countries, within<br />

<strong>the</strong> textile sector, it is clothing that dominates<br />

in terms of value of producti<strong>on</strong> and<br />

employment. This structural element is<br />

significant since <strong>the</strong> clothing sector is<br />

more labour intensive than textiles in<br />

general, a matter that impacts <strong>the</strong> level<br />

of formal employment. TC producti<strong>on</strong><br />

in Morocco rose to 15% of <strong>the</strong> value of<br />

manufactured goods but accounted for<br />

45% of employment in 2003. Tunisia<br />

is in <strong>the</strong> same situati<strong>on</strong> where producti<strong>on</strong><br />

in this sector represents <strong>on</strong>e third<br />

of manufactured goods while absorbing<br />

more than half <strong>the</strong> employment<br />

and accounting for 7.1% of GDP (EIU,<br />

2003).<br />

It is necessary to underline certain characteristics<br />

of <strong>the</strong> TC sector in Maghreb<br />

countries that are an important part in<br />

informal employment and <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>duct of


firms that resort to n<strong>on</strong>-declared labour<br />

in order to reduce costs. The origin of<br />

difficulties related to competitiveness<br />

c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>ted by <strong>the</strong>se countries lies in <strong>the</strong><br />

cost of manpower which is significantly<br />

higher than that borne by <strong>the</strong>ir Asian<br />

competitors. In 2002, average wages in<br />

<strong>the</strong> textile sector in Morocco and Tunisia<br />

was nearly fivefold those in China and<br />

equivalent to those registered in certain<br />

eastern countries such as Slovakia,<br />

Est<strong>on</strong>ia or even Turkey. With <strong>the</strong> end of<br />

<strong>the</strong> multi-fiber agreement and its impact<br />

<strong>on</strong> quotas imposed <strong>on</strong> Asian competitors,<br />

it was inevitable that Maghreb countries<br />

would suffer from competitive pressures<br />

and lay-offs.<br />

In view of <strong>the</strong> structure and employment<br />

c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s in <strong>the</strong> TC sector in<br />

Morocco, female employment prevailed<br />

as well as informal producti<strong>on</strong>, young<br />

employees and/or unmarried with a<br />

modest level of educati<strong>on</strong> without regular<br />

schooling and who were often <strong>on</strong>ly<br />

temporarily employed. In 1999, 61%<br />

of wage earners and 90% of household<br />

workers were women. Employers have<br />

a marked preference for single women<br />

with no family resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities and who<br />

are easy to train. According to Bouquia<br />

(2002), 59% of employees in this sector<br />

are below 25 years of age against<br />

45% of employees. N<strong>on</strong>e<strong>the</strong>less <strong>the</strong>y<br />

do have certain family resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities<br />

such as c<strong>on</strong>tributing to family expenses<br />

to a large extent. Temporary work is<br />

widespread in particular in SMEs. This<br />

structure of employment mainly results<br />

from <strong>the</strong> orientati<strong>on</strong> toward exporting<br />

<strong>the</strong> activity of formal sector firms and<br />

dependence vis-à-vis orders coming<br />

from European distributors. The latter<br />

prefer calling up<strong>on</strong> geographically close<br />

companies since delivery delays have<br />

-35-<br />

to be brief (Belghazi). If a product is<br />

sold more rapidly than expected and<br />

restocking is necessary, firms based in<br />

Morocco are apparently capable of satisfying<br />

<strong>the</strong>se c<strong>on</strong>straints.<br />

Surveys undertaken for <strong>the</strong> <strong>Femise</strong> study<br />

indicate that if <strong>the</strong> labour force is relatively<br />

young in Morocco, this was not <strong>the</strong><br />

case for Tunisia and Algeria where workers<br />

are mostly below 30 years of age.<br />

On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, here as well, female<br />

employment is dominant. However,<br />

in Tunisia, where average per capita<br />

income is nearly two times higher than<br />

that in Morocco, women’s motivati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

to seek employment are more pers<strong>on</strong>al<br />

such as to earn enough m<strong>on</strong>ey to buy<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir marriage trousseau.<br />

A revealing crisis that broke out<br />

before <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> multi-fiber<br />

agreement<br />

Recent tendencies of Maghreb countries<br />

indicate that producti<strong>on</strong> began to decline<br />

at <strong>the</strong> beginning of <strong>the</strong> 1990s in Algeria,<br />

in 1999 in Morocco and 2002 in Tunisia,<br />

and that employment followed <strong>the</strong> evoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

of producti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The TC industry crisis appeared at <strong>the</strong><br />

close of <strong>the</strong> 1990s in Morocco. Lay-offs<br />

began to take place. Revaluati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

Moroccan Dirham and uncertainties related<br />

to <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> multi-fiber agreement<br />

engendered a decline in investments,<br />

more lay-offs as well as losses<br />

in some European markets. Expansi<strong>on</strong><br />

in employment in <strong>the</strong> TC sector suffered<br />

from unfavorable changes in demand and<br />

price. In <strong>the</strong> first half of <strong>2005</strong>, Morocco<br />

registered a loss of 60 000 jobs whereas<br />

<strong>the</strong> workforce in 2002 stood at 202 000<br />

pers<strong>on</strong>s[22]. Morocco is also c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>-


ted with problems in its own market,<br />

reflected in <strong>the</strong> drop in prices and this<br />

explains <strong>the</strong> disappointing performance<br />

of this sector. In <strong>the</strong> third quarter of<br />

<strong>2005</strong>, producti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> clothing industry<br />

lost -8.9% as compared to 2004;<br />

<strong>the</strong> textile branch and lea<strong>the</strong>r reached<br />

-0.8% whereas it had progressed by<br />

5% in 2004. In <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>on</strong>d quarter of<br />

<strong>2005</strong>, exports of ready-made clothing<br />

and hosiery yielded 10.8% and 17.9%<br />

respectively. This produced a reducti<strong>on</strong><br />

of -3.3% in value-added of “textile and<br />

lea<strong>the</strong>r”[23].<br />

As for Tunisia, it overcame <strong>the</strong><br />

slowdown which occurred during 1980s.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, growth in <strong>the</strong> sector surpassed<br />

that of manufactured exports.<br />

The country managed to preserve its<br />

share in <strong>the</strong> European market, which<br />

attained a peak of 6.1% in 1998 despite<br />

<strong>the</strong> arrival of new competitors (Morocco,<br />

Turkey, Eastern European countries).<br />

This is not <strong>the</strong> case since <strong>the</strong> end of<br />

<strong>the</strong> multi-fiber agreement which was<br />

followed by a wait-and-see approach,<br />

uncertainty, slow reforms while at <strong>the</strong><br />

same time large exporting countries<br />

stepped up <strong>the</strong>ir investments. 79% of<br />

Tunisian enterprises of <strong>the</strong> sector produce<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly for export [24] and never<strong>the</strong>less<br />

find difficulty in keeping up with competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

with Asian producers in foreign<br />

and domestic markets.<br />

As of <strong>2005</strong>, <strong>the</strong> producti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> TC<br />

sector faltered while <strong>the</strong> manufacturing<br />

sector in its totality progressed thanks to<br />

diversificati<strong>on</strong> toward automobiles and<br />

electr<strong>on</strong>ics.<br />

In Algeria, <strong>the</strong> sector entered into a<br />

crisis before <strong>the</strong> crises in Tunisia and<br />

Morocco following restructuring al<strong>on</strong>g<br />

-36-<br />

<strong>the</strong> way to a market ec<strong>on</strong>omy. In <strong>the</strong><br />

1980s, working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s were relatively<br />

good, particularly in <strong>the</strong> public<br />

sector but less so for employees in <strong>the</strong><br />

private sector especially SMEs where<br />

workers were replaced by apprentices<br />

or household workers in order to reduce<br />

producti<strong>on</strong> costs. In <strong>the</strong> 1990s, ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

restructuring engendered a wave of<br />

company closures and reduced producti<strong>on</strong><br />

(1500 enterprises were involved).<br />

Employment in this sector declined by<br />

60%, wages fell and occasi<strong>on</strong>al work<br />

increased. Legislati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

(health and security norms, social<br />

coverage, working hours, etc.) was less<br />

scrupulously observed. In <strong>the</strong> same<br />

vein, paid holidays were abolished or<br />

reduced, training programmes aband<strong>on</strong>ed<br />

and canteens or medical centers<br />

closed down. Workers were not declared<br />

and <strong>the</strong> practice of paying wages in cash<br />

spread.<br />

Fragility of <strong>the</strong> sector is essentially<br />

industrial<br />

The textile-clothing industry in MPs is<br />

very fragile, because, except for Turkey,<br />

it appears that:<br />

√ These countries were not able to<br />

forge a network, which is to establish<br />

direct relati<strong>on</strong>s with clientsretailers.<br />

Through networking, activities<br />

could be segmented and localized<br />

in different countries without<br />

seriously impacting <strong>the</strong> price of <strong>the</strong><br />

final product insofar as <strong>the</strong> cost of<br />

transporting intermediate products is<br />

relatively low. The strategic variables<br />

here are <strong>the</strong> time of transport and <strong>the</strong><br />

cost of stocking incurred by each c<strong>on</strong>tributor<br />

in <strong>the</strong> network. This explains<br />

increased externalizing of operati<strong>on</strong>s


of cutting and assembling that allow<br />

taking advantage of specific manufacturing<br />

in each locati<strong>on</strong>, both <strong>on</strong> a city<br />

scale or <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> scale of <strong>on</strong>e or more<br />

countries.<br />

√ Their companies were incapable of<br />

ameliorating <strong>the</strong>ir positi<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong><br />

value chain. The central positi<strong>on</strong> in<br />

<strong>the</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> value chain<br />

in <strong>the</strong> textile sector is held by <strong>the</strong><br />

distributor in that he c<strong>on</strong>trols <strong>the</strong><br />

strategic variables which are c<strong>on</strong>cepti<strong>on</strong><br />

of products and knowledge of <strong>the</strong><br />

market. Hence it is at this level that<br />

more value is created (table x12).<br />

The price of an article can be three<br />

to fifteen times its price ex-factory.<br />

The difference is explained not by <strong>the</strong><br />

quality of <strong>the</strong> fabric or a significantly<br />

higher time of executi<strong>on</strong> but by <strong>the</strong><br />

cost of promoti<strong>on</strong>, distributi<strong>on</strong> and<br />

“revenue” generated by <strong>the</strong> trademark.<br />

Moreover, inputs, such as <strong>the</strong><br />

fabric which represents nearly 60%<br />

of <strong>the</strong> cost price of a garment, are<br />

<strong>the</strong> essential elements of a product’s<br />

competitiveness and not <strong>the</strong> cost of<br />

manufacture[25].<br />

These are a few facts that indicate<br />

<strong>the</strong> method of organizati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> TC<br />

sector which underlines <strong>the</strong> difference<br />

that exists between <strong>the</strong> enterprise that<br />

exports under its own local trademark<br />

and which c<strong>on</strong>trols and can capture a<br />

large share of <strong>the</strong> value, and <strong>the</strong> subc<strong>on</strong>tractor<br />

who produces <strong>the</strong> same products<br />

for a foreign client who provides<br />

him with <strong>the</strong> model and fabric (table<br />

x12). Competitiveness of <strong>the</strong> former<br />

rests <strong>on</strong> factors o<strong>the</strong>r than cost (collecti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

fame), whereas <strong>the</strong> latter depends<br />

<strong>on</strong> cost and time required. A third actor<br />

can intervene between <strong>the</strong> first two, <strong>the</strong><br />

-37-<br />

co-c<strong>on</strong>tractor who makes an article from<br />

fabrics he has purchased and whose<br />

competitiveness refers to his knowledge<br />

of <strong>the</strong> market for basic products.<br />

These two viewpoints, <strong>the</strong> value chain<br />

and <strong>the</strong> network, are not entirely dissociated<br />

from each o<strong>the</strong>r. The positi<strong>on</strong><br />

that enterprises in a country can occupy<br />

al<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> value chain depends <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

level of development of <strong>the</strong> network.<br />

The more an industry is diversified, <strong>the</strong><br />

more an enterprise can easily find <strong>the</strong><br />

raw material required in its country, <strong>the</strong><br />

more co-c<strong>on</strong>tractor activities could be<br />

multiplied.<br />

The multi-fiber agreement and trade<br />

preference accords, while curbing immigrati<strong>on</strong><br />

and stimulating <strong>the</strong> emergence<br />

of developing countries, have fur<strong>the</strong>red<br />

<strong>the</strong> appearance of “specialized clothing”<br />

in neighboring European countries which<br />

in turn have permitted an increase in <strong>the</strong><br />

export of European fabrics. Incoming<br />

products to <strong>the</strong> European market without<br />

customs tariffs must respect rules of<br />

origin. MPs, except Turkey, having had<br />

no right to install a network <strong>on</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

territory were obliged to import fabrics<br />

from Europe.<br />

However, this movement caused fragmentati<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong> market. The four principal<br />

exporters (China, Mexico, India,<br />

and Turkey) account for 38% of global<br />

exports followed by twenty countries to<br />

<strong>the</strong> tune of 1% worldwide. Examining<br />

<strong>the</strong> cost of wages, competitiveness and<br />

industrial performance of diverse protag<strong>on</strong>ists<br />

indicates that positi<strong>on</strong>s occupied<br />

by some in <strong>the</strong> global market are<br />

artificial and solely maintained by <strong>the</strong><br />

existence of <strong>the</strong> multi-fiber agreement.<br />

Countries that abolished quotas have


egistered a formidable c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> of √ countries whose exporters, essenti-<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir imports, hence <strong>the</strong> two following ally sub-c<strong>on</strong>tractors, have a radius of<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>figurati<strong>on</strong>s:<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>al acti<strong>on</strong> (European or American<br />

market), but where <strong>the</strong> TC sector<br />

√ countries whose TC exporters are accounts for more than 40% of <strong>the</strong><br />

present in all markets, who rely <strong>on</strong> country’s exports, even if its share in<br />

abundant and diversified nati<strong>on</strong>al tex- added value is small (weak productitile<br />

offer;<br />

vity, unskilled jobs), and is <strong>on</strong>e of <strong>the</strong><br />

Table X10: Cost structure of clothing industry in several countries, 2001 (% of <strong>the</strong><br />

producti<strong>on</strong>)<br />

Unqualified<br />

manpower<br />

Qualified<br />

manpower<br />

Capital Value-added Inputs Imported inputs<br />

Canada 25,9 5,0 10,2 41,2 58,8 19,8<br />

USA 21,0 5,8 5,8 32,6 67,4 13,8<br />

France 21,6 4,7 8,8 35,0 65,0 24,3<br />

Italy 14,3 3,1 16,4 33,8 66,2 13,5<br />

Japan 21,9 4,0 11,2 37,1 62,9 7,8<br />

H<strong>on</strong>g K<strong>on</strong>g, China 22,6 7,9 12,9 43,4 56,6 13,0<br />

Korea 15,0 2,9 4,7 22,6 77,4 15,9<br />

China Taipei 20,8 3,5 6,0 30,3 69,7 10,9<br />

China 18,2 2,5 12,2 32,9 67,1 6,7<br />

India 21,1 2,9 7,8 31,8 68,2 1,8<br />

Vietnam 9,0 1,2 3,8 14,0 86,0 40,4<br />

Czech Republic 21,1 3,2 9,9 34,1 65,9 28,9<br />

Morocco 14,6 2,1 10,9 27,6 72,4 37,9<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong>, study FEM22-34<br />

Table X11: Cost structure of textile industry in several countries, 2001 (% of <strong>the</strong><br />

producti<strong>on</strong>)<br />

Unqualified<br />

manpower<br />

Qualified<br />

manpower<br />

Capital Value-added Inputs Imported inputs<br />

Canada 22,7 3,1 10,3 36,1 63,9 24,2<br />

USA 19,5 4,2 10,3 34,0 66,0 9,7<br />

France 13,8 3,7 7,2 24,7 75,3 22,0<br />

Italy 11,8 3,2 7,2 24,7 75,3 22,0<br />

Japan 17,6 6,6 7,0 31,2 68,8 11,2<br />

H<strong>on</strong>g K<strong>on</strong>g, China 9,0 3,9 10,8 23,8 76,2 5,8<br />

Korea 12,0 2,3 16,2 29,5 70,5 20,0<br />

China Taipei 10,4 3,3 8,3 22,0 78,0 10,2<br />

China 9,7 1,6 12,0 23,2 76,8 8,1<br />

India 17,8 2,8 6,7 27,3 72,7 4,0<br />

Vietnam 10,2 1,6 12,4 24,3 75,7 34,3<br />

Czech Republic 13,0 1,8 13,8 28,7 71,3 35,1<br />

Morocco 5,8 0,9 6,2 13,0 87,0 44,3<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong>, study FEM22-34<br />

Table X12: Value added in each step of <strong>the</strong> added values chain (from <strong>the</strong> fibers to<br />

<strong>the</strong> commercializati<strong>on</strong>)<br />

Stage<br />

Shirt<br />

Fiber threading Weaving Making Distributi<strong>on</strong><br />

Unit 1kg 0,8 kg 4,85 m 2,1 shirts 2,1 shirts<br />

Value in USD 1 2,0 4,7 9,8 22,7<br />

Value-added (USD) 1,0 2,6 5,1 12,9<br />

% of final value 4% 5% 12% 23% 57%<br />

Trousers<br />

Unit 1 0,75 kg 2,3 m 2 trousers 2 trousers<br />

Value in USD 1 2,2 7,5 14,5 37,5<br />

Value-added (USD) 1,2 5,2 7 23<br />

% of final value 3% 3% 14% 19% 61%<br />

Source : Kurt Salom<strong>on</strong> Associates, in Textile Outlook internati<strong>on</strong>al, January 2004, cited in Study <strong>Femise</strong><br />

FEM22-34.<br />

-38


main industrial employers, is capa-<br />

ble of compensating <strong>the</strong> weakness<br />

of o<strong>the</strong>r exporters and drawing FDI<br />

(Bangladesh, Cambodia, Egypt, Syria,<br />

Tunisia).<br />

In terms of competitiveness, MPs blame<br />

several types of handicaps:<br />

√ They cannot compete in terms of<br />

wages with Asian countries where<br />

salaries vary between 50 (Myanmar)<br />

and 100 Euros (China) although <strong>the</strong>y<br />

can do so with European countries<br />

(5% to 15% of European costs).<br />

√ They suffer from significantly unqualified<br />

manpower and its negative<br />

impact <strong>on</strong> productivity.<br />

√ Rigidity of <strong>the</strong> labour market hinders This phenomen<strong>on</strong> is due in particular to<br />

reallocati<strong>on</strong> of manpower.<br />

<strong>the</strong> slackness of investments accompanied<br />

by increasing uncertainties regarding<br />

√ Evoluti<strong>on</strong> of real exchange rates wei- <strong>the</strong> magnitude of harmful c<strong>on</strong>sequences<br />

ghs <strong>on</strong> external competitiveness and caused by <strong>the</strong> aboliti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> multi-<br />

<strong>the</strong> evoluti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> US dollar has fiber agreement. The crisis in <strong>the</strong> tex-<br />

helped Asian countries in European tile-clothing sector in Maghreb countries<br />

markets.<br />

probably had a self-fulfilling dimensi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Figures of machine purchases highlight<br />

Needless to say, <strong>the</strong>y have <strong>the</strong> advan- this. Between 2000 and 2003, when<br />

tage of proximity to <strong>the</strong> European mar- China bought half of <strong>the</strong> yarn equipment<br />

ket, not that <strong>the</strong> cost of transportati<strong>on</strong> (l<strong>on</strong>g fiber) sold in <strong>the</strong> world, and India<br />

is particularly low, but it still allows and Pakistan <strong>on</strong>e quarter for short fiber,<br />

for better reactivity. Dispatching by air, western Europe acquired 18 000 looms<br />

Figures 5 and 6: textile-clothing investments in % of turnover (Tunisia and<br />

Morocco)<br />

-39-<br />

which represents an additi<strong>on</strong>al cost of<br />

1 Euro per article and which does penalize<br />

medium range or higher articles,<br />

can never<strong>the</strong>less undermine this advantage<br />

(10% of Chinese exports). Cultural<br />

proximity remains.<br />

A troubling factor is <strong>the</strong> decline of<br />

<strong>the</strong> share of Maghreb countries in <strong>the</strong><br />

European market since 1998: 5.4% in<br />

1998 against 4.9% in 2004 for Morocco,<br />

and 6.1% against 5.2% for <strong>the</strong> same<br />

years for Tunisia. These bad performances<br />

cannot be attributed to China’s<br />

progress in global markets following<br />

entry in WTO, or liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of certain<br />

exchanges of goods because <strong>the</strong>se do<br />

not figure am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> principal exports of<br />

<strong>the</strong>se countries.


and Turkey 11 000, more than India,<br />

Bangladesh, Pakistan and Thailand put<br />

toge<strong>the</strong>r. The effort exerted by Turkey is<br />

c<strong>on</strong>siderable despite <strong>the</strong> very grave ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

crisis it was experiencing during<br />

this period. GDP lost 7%, 40% of stock<br />

was renewed. Egypt and Syria followed<br />

sluggishly while Tunisia and Morocco<br />

made very few investments.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sequences of <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong><br />

multi-fiber agreement<br />

Exchanges in <strong>the</strong> TC sector are governed<br />

by <strong>the</strong> General Agreement <strong>on</strong> Tariffs and<br />

Trade of <strong>the</strong> 1st of January <strong>2005</strong>, which<br />

put an end to <strong>the</strong> system of import<br />

quotas, which had been in force for 40<br />

years. Liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of textile exchanges<br />

that was so dreaded is a reality today to<br />

which MPs, like <strong>the</strong> EU and <strong>the</strong> United<br />

States must adapt. Undoubtedly, in <strong>the</strong><br />

face of <strong>the</strong> immediate oppositi<strong>on</strong> engendered<br />

by <strong>the</strong> first effects of <strong>the</strong> end of<br />

<strong>the</strong> multi-fiber agreement, quotas <strong>on</strong><br />

Chinese imports were temporarily reintroduced<br />

in spring <strong>2005</strong>. MPs also obtained<br />

a supplementary delay of two years<br />

to restructure this sector and prepare<br />

to c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>t Asian competitiveness. After<br />

January 2008, <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly protecti<strong>on</strong> that<br />

will remain will be a tariff of 12.4% in<br />

<strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong> EU (with a maximum of<br />

13.4%) and 12.8% for <strong>the</strong> United States<br />

(with a maximum of 29.7%).<br />

The c<strong>on</strong>sequence of raising quotas <strong>on</strong><br />

European industry is a very tangible setback<br />

for its exports in terms of yarn and<br />

fabric which will climb to nearly 15%.<br />

For <strong>the</strong> United States and <strong>the</strong> EU, <strong>the</strong><br />

danger is not so much an invasi<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir markets by products manufactured<br />

in China than <strong>the</strong> significant reducti<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong>ir yarn and fabric exports. These<br />

-40-<br />

products feed clothing industries in central<br />

Europe, sou<strong>the</strong>rn Mediterranean and<br />

Central America who are subjected to<br />

<strong>the</strong> full blast of competing Chinese<br />

goods. The evoluti<strong>on</strong> of European and<br />

American yarn and fabric exports are but<br />

<strong>the</strong> effects resulting from <strong>the</strong> difficulties<br />

c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>ting <strong>the</strong> industries of <strong>the</strong>se countries.<br />

Regarding MPs, <strong>the</strong> new situati<strong>on</strong> carries<br />

both risks because exchanges with<br />

textile industries of Maghreb with EU in<br />

particular were relatively well protected<br />

by this system as well as possible<br />

new opportunities which <strong>the</strong>se countries<br />

should seize. This demands a c<strong>on</strong>siderable<br />

effort to adapt in <strong>the</strong> face of competitors<br />

who have belatedly, but more resolutely,<br />

engaged in <strong>the</strong> road to reform.<br />

Opportunities and risks can be measured<br />

by some figures. Bangladesh, Sri Lanka,<br />

Vietnam, Mauritania and Cambodia have<br />

registered rapid pace of growth in this<br />

sector. China was <strong>the</strong> top exporter of<br />

textiles-clothing during 1995-2002 and<br />

its share in <strong>the</strong> global market rose from<br />

22.5% to 30% in <strong>the</strong> clothing sector<br />

and 16% to 22% in textiles. On <strong>the</strong><br />

o<strong>the</strong>r hand, numerous industries did not<br />

manage to adapt <strong>the</strong>mselves and survive<br />

changes of competiti<strong>on</strong>. Clo<strong>the</strong>s sector<br />

in Bangladesh could be <strong>the</strong> next victim.<br />

According to IMF report, <strong>the</strong> country<br />

could lose <strong>on</strong>e quarter of its exports,<br />

i.e. at least 2.3 milli<strong>on</strong> jobs, after quotas<br />

are eliminated. North Africa, Turkey<br />

and eastern European countries could<br />

be evicted from <strong>the</strong> European market<br />

similar to Mexican and African producers<br />

from <strong>the</strong> American market. The rapid<br />

success of Cambodia, where garments<br />

were <strong>the</strong> leading manufactured product<br />

is equally at peril.


The impact of lifting quotas is often<br />

measured with a bias toward minimizing<br />

Chinese competitiveness. In fact, <strong>the</strong><br />

measures are realized based <strong>on</strong> similarities<br />

between exportati<strong>on</strong> structures<br />

of countries that enter into competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

in EU markets, tilted, in <strong>the</strong> case of<br />

China by using data <strong>on</strong> clothing exports<br />

towards <strong>the</strong> EU which reflects <strong>the</strong> existence<br />

of quotas. In order to circumvent<br />

this problem, <strong>on</strong>e can calculate <strong>the</strong><br />

index by taking as reference China-<br />

Japan exchanges whose structure is not<br />

too far from that of <strong>the</strong> EU, but whose<br />

aggregate does not suffer from <strong>the</strong> same<br />

limits. It <strong>the</strong>refore appears that potential<br />

competitiveness of Chinese exports over<br />

those of MPs is formidable and that MPs<br />

compete am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong>mselves by blocs<br />

(Morocco and Tunisia, but not Maghreb-<br />

Machrek and Turkey with MPs). However<br />

competitiveness is less str<strong>on</strong>g with eastern<br />

European countries who are new<br />

members of <strong>the</strong> European Uni<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The effects expected of change are<br />

alarming by <strong>the</strong>ir importance, even if<br />

measures are always indicative. For<br />

example, it is expected that Morocco’s<br />

share in <strong>the</strong> European market will fall<br />

-41-<br />

from 5% to 4% in <strong>2005</strong> due to <strong>the</strong> rise in<br />

EU imports from Asia, in particular from<br />

China. However, <strong>the</strong> volume of textile<br />

exports in <strong>the</strong>se countries is high and<br />

weighs up<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> share of Moroccan and<br />

Tunisian value-added in total producti<strong>on</strong><br />

and it does not allow <strong>the</strong> use of <strong>the</strong><br />

currency devaluati<strong>on</strong> weap<strong>on</strong> to boost<br />

internati<strong>on</strong>al competitiveness.<br />

The experience of 2002 of significant<br />

growth of shares in <strong>the</strong> European market<br />

of eleven Chinese products affected<br />

by <strong>the</strong> lifting of quotas following China’s<br />

entry into WTO (+13% to 45%) is enlightening<br />

and heralds what will undoubtedly<br />

occur in 2 years time. On eight<br />

clothing products, China has registered<br />

ast<strong>on</strong>ishing progress and equally surprising<br />

drop in prices: -12% to -80% of<br />

unit prices in Euros (figures 6 and 7).<br />

This is <strong>the</strong> result of suppressing quotas<br />

that involve costs and <strong>the</strong> reform<br />

of Chinese industry as State owned<br />

enterprises lose <strong>the</strong>ir privileges, <strong>the</strong>reby<br />

permitting o<strong>the</strong>rs to progress as well as<br />

reducing intermediaries.<br />

Recognizing that <strong>the</strong> TC sector was <strong>the</strong><br />

motor for development of producti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

Table X13: competiti<strong>on</strong> indicator of textile-clothing sector, MP, new members,<br />

China, with figures of 2003<br />

Romania Tunisia Morocco Poland Czech Republic Egypt Syria China China*<br />

Turkey 0,5 0,6 0,7 0,5 0,6 0,7 0,8 0,3 0,8<br />

Romania 0,7 0,8 0,9 0,8 0,4 0,4 0,4 0,7<br />

Tunisia 0,9 0,8 0,8 0,4 0,2 0,3 0,6<br />

Morocco 0,9 0,8 0,6 0,5 0,4 0,7<br />

Poland 0,8 0,4 0,3 0,4 0,6<br />

Czech Republic 0,0 0,0 0,4 0,8<br />

Egypt 0 0,3 0,7<br />

Syria 0,2 0,6<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong>, study 22-36<br />

Note: The indicator used is called Cos Cos. To compare <strong>the</strong> structure of exports to <strong>the</strong> EU of clothing<br />

articles of a country i to that of a country j, we have c<strong>on</strong>sidered <strong>the</strong> vectors Eik et Ejk for k=1,...,n<br />

(n being <strong>the</strong> 246 items of <strong>the</strong> HS nomenclature HS for clothing) that represent <strong>the</strong> exports of <strong>the</strong> two<br />

studied countries in this sector. The “distance” between <strong>the</strong>se two vectors is obtained by calculating <strong>the</strong><br />

cosines of <strong>the</strong>ir angles that varies from 0 (total dissimilarity) and 1 (total similarity).


employment and exportati<strong>on</strong>, and given<br />

that socio-ec<strong>on</strong>omic characteristics of<br />

<strong>the</strong> sector, <strong>the</strong> competitive shock resulting<br />

from changes in competiti<strong>on</strong> circumstances<br />

in internati<strong>on</strong>al markets,<br />

can be translated as:<br />

(i) movement of manpower from <strong>the</strong> √ Because firms close down or down-<br />

formal to <strong>the</strong> informal sector of <strong>the</strong> size owing to <strong>on</strong>going restructuring,<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omy (SME-SMI and independent it is difficult to find a job in <strong>the</strong> same<br />

entrepreneurs),<br />

sector <strong>the</strong>reby prol<strong>on</strong>ging <strong>the</strong> period<br />

of unemployment. Thus ec<strong>on</strong>omic dif-<br />

(ii) a decrease in productivity of work as ficulties increase even if this is not <strong>the</strong><br />

a result of transferring formal man- case with all workers. On <strong>the</strong> whole,<br />

power to sectors of exchangeable surveys c<strong>on</strong>firm <strong>the</strong> results of o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

and n<strong>on</strong>-exchangeable goods fol- studies whereby informal employment<br />

lowing a decline in hourly wages or is gaining ground in North Africa.<br />

working time,<br />

√ It is quite improbable that <strong>the</strong> clo-<br />

(iii) an evoluti<strong>on</strong> of wages that depends thing sector in <strong>the</strong> three countries can<br />

<strong>on</strong> capital intensity and qualificati<strong>on</strong> absorb workers who were fired during<br />

in diverse branches of producti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> past years or who will be regar-<br />

SMEs.<br />

dless of <strong>the</strong> effectiveness of restructuring<br />

and possible improvements.<br />

A study undertaken by a <strong>Femise</strong> team Moreover, all that could be d<strong>on</strong>e to<br />

indicates, especially through its sur- fur<strong>the</strong>r increase <strong>the</strong> competitiveness<br />

veys[26], that:<br />

Figures 6 and 7: rising of China share in EU imports<br />

and fall of unit prices<br />

√ C<strong>on</strong>sequences of loss of<br />

Increase of <strong>the</strong> China share in EU imports And fall in unit prices (in <strong>euro</strong>s)<br />

employment vary within and<br />

between countries according<br />

to structural characteristics<br />

of <strong>the</strong> three countries and<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir ec<strong>on</strong>omic development<br />

standards but that insecurity<br />

rises.<br />

√ With regard to working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

<strong>the</strong> idea that <strong>the</strong>re<br />

exists a clear dichotomy<br />

between formal and informal<br />

sector firms appears to<br />

be false. There exists a c<strong>on</strong>tinuum<br />

of enterprises whose<br />

characteristics and c<strong>on</strong>duct Source: <strong>Femise</strong>, study FEM22-34<br />

-42-<br />

are embodied in a manner to carry<br />

out <strong>the</strong>ir activity partly in c<strong>on</strong>formity<br />

with formal legislati<strong>on</strong>s and regulati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

and at <strong>the</strong> same time seeks to<br />

bypass certain obligati<strong>on</strong>s, particularly<br />

those pertaining to employment.


and efficiency should be realized,<br />

according to <strong>the</strong> authors, a strategy<br />

to absorb <strong>the</strong> excess workforce in <strong>the</strong><br />

clothing sector must be elaborated<br />

and promptly implemented.<br />

At <strong>the</strong> end of two years during which<br />

<strong>the</strong> EU will impose new quotas, as will<br />

<strong>the</strong> United States, Chinese exporters will<br />

have organized <strong>the</strong> rise of its range of<br />

products and c<strong>on</strong>verged <strong>the</strong>ir specializati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

with those of MPs. For <strong>the</strong> latter,<br />

it is imperative to exploit this respite in<br />

order to face <strong>the</strong> shock looming in 2008<br />

and which could mark <strong>the</strong> beginning of<br />

<strong>the</strong> end of textiles in MPs.<br />

How to manage textiles after Multifiber<br />

According to what preceded, <strong>the</strong> following<br />

questi<strong>on</strong> is naturally posed: is it<br />

possible to prepare a “soft landing” for<br />

<strong>the</strong> textile sector in MPs, to give time to<br />

identify activities of <strong>the</strong> industrial sector<br />

and services that could take over <strong>the</strong><br />

employment charge from <strong>the</strong> TC industry<br />

as well as its export and productivity<br />

gains? The above menti<strong>on</strong>ed study proposed<br />

<strong>the</strong> following policy recommendati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

whose beneficial effects could<br />

rapidly materialize:<br />

√ Maghreb countries must bear in mind<br />

three new elements to guide <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

restructuring strategy: firstly, changes<br />

in c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

competitiveness, sec<strong>on</strong>dly, a trend<br />

that is more and more marked in <strong>the</strong><br />

EU, namely to c<strong>on</strong>centrate its supply<br />

sources in Asia (China, India), finally,<br />

modificati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> role of textileclothing<br />

producers, who are geographically<br />

close to <strong>the</strong> EU but whose<br />

cost of producti<strong>on</strong> is higher and who<br />

-43-<br />

must be capable of providing reduced<br />

series in very short time (mid-seas<strong>on</strong><br />

producti<strong>on</strong> or need for restocking due<br />

to a greater demand than predicted,<br />

etc.). Meanwhile, it is necessary for<br />

EU countries to ensure <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>stant<br />

quality of <strong>the</strong>ir products. Therefore<br />

<strong>the</strong>y will c<strong>on</strong>tinue to impose stringent<br />

c<strong>on</strong>trol <strong>on</strong> design and origin of inputs<br />

(mainly from outside North Africa).<br />

The level of producti<strong>on</strong> for export<br />

by North Africa will by virtue of <strong>the</strong><br />

above, probably c<strong>on</strong>tinue to be intensive<br />

in importati<strong>on</strong> and will depend <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> capacity of firms to satisfy new<br />

orders in brief periods, to diversify<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir producti<strong>on</strong>, and to move from<br />

<strong>on</strong>e product to ano<strong>the</strong>r. The ensuing<br />

c<strong>on</strong>straints are that <strong>on</strong>e will need to<br />

sub-c<strong>on</strong>tract certain activities as in<br />

Morocco’s case, and streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong><br />

tendency for occasi<strong>on</strong>al employment.<br />

This is also a characteristic of <strong>the</strong><br />

Moroccan clothing sector. In Tunisia,<br />

where <strong>the</strong> majority of companies are<br />

used to produce for trademarks such<br />

as Levis and Lee Cooper, <strong>the</strong>re is<br />

scope for enterprises with <strong>the</strong> means<br />

to meet a more punctual demand (as<br />

in Egypt and Jordan).<br />

√ As dem<strong>on</strong>strated by Morocco, development<br />

of niche producti<strong>on</strong> oriented<br />

toward <strong>the</strong> parties that generate relatively<br />

higher revenues in <strong>the</strong> European<br />

market is possible. O<strong>the</strong>r countries<br />

should possibly copy this trend even<br />

if attaining this type of slot (niche) is<br />

not easy. Tunisia is actually experiencing<br />

problems in taking this turn due<br />

to lack of originality in producti<strong>on</strong>, a<br />

fear in changing entrepreneurs as well<br />

as delays in adopting modern management<br />

techniques (Zghal, 1999).<br />

The keys for succeeding in restruc-


turing <strong>the</strong> sector are: ameliorating<br />

<strong>the</strong> quality of products, by adopting<br />

innovative and modern management<br />

techniques. In this domain, <strong>the</strong> EU<br />

can assist firms in Maghreb countries<br />

(i) by helping to identify opportunities<br />

of existing niche markets (possibility<br />

to exploit specific knowledge and<br />

savoir-faire in embroidery and o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

decorative techniques destined to<br />

certain markets such as kaftans and<br />

lea<strong>the</strong>r clo<strong>the</strong>s, embroidered marriage<br />

gowns, evening dresses utilizing<br />

European styles and embellished with<br />

traditi<strong>on</strong>al embroidery of MPs), (ii)<br />

by offering necessary funds to start<br />

joint EU-MED activities in <strong>the</strong> clothing<br />

sector, (iii) by encouraging innovati<strong>on</strong><br />

within SME-SMI, (iv) by assisting<br />

firms in Maghreb to undertake studies<br />

<strong>on</strong> EU markets, (v) by encouraging<br />

more efficient management via<br />

training programmes for Maghrebian<br />

entrepreneurs, namely in European<br />

companies (<strong>the</strong>se programmes could<br />

be disseminated to all MPs and sectors).<br />

√ The fact that it should be relevant to<br />

intervene at <strong>the</strong> level of SMEs signifies<br />

that policies in favour of facilitating<br />

exchanges, acquiring competences in<br />

design and producti<strong>on</strong>, micro-financing<br />

possibilities, obtaining technical<br />

advice and encouragement to <strong>the</strong><br />

groupings of enterprises could be<br />

very effective in <strong>the</strong> short-term; <strong>the</strong><br />

objective of <strong>the</strong>se initiatives is <strong>the</strong><br />

development of SMEs in <strong>the</strong> clothing<br />

sector, but not <strong>on</strong>ly those.<br />

√ It will also be beneficial to promote<br />

knowledge of workers in <strong>the</strong><br />

fields of design and producti<strong>on</strong>s in<br />

close cooperati<strong>on</strong> with enterprises in<br />

-44-<br />

order to ensure jobs for all but not<br />

to create excessive pers<strong>on</strong>nel which<br />

is likely to increase unemployment.<br />

Tunisia already adopted initiatives<br />

in this regard by creating schools<br />

for technical educati<strong>on</strong>, particularly<br />

in design, specifically related to <strong>the</strong><br />

textile-clothing sector. Training capabilities<br />

though are not fully exploited.<br />

Therefore, regi<strong>on</strong>al cooperati<strong>on</strong><br />

should be established for developing<br />

training instituti<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

√ An essential role that should be<br />

played by government if it wishes to<br />

assist enterprises in adapting to new<br />

competitive c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s is to simplify<br />

customs formalities. Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness<br />

of firms in exportati<strong>on</strong> is often hindered<br />

by administrative obstacles that<br />

delay passage through customs of<br />

imported intermediary goods used in<br />

<strong>the</strong> manufacture of <strong>the</strong>se products.<br />

Morocco which is modernizing it customs<br />

in cooperati<strong>on</strong> with <strong>the</strong> World<br />

Bank, must take into account this<br />

dimensi<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>sequently a study <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> opini<strong>on</strong> of firms <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> effectiveness<br />

of customs reform in Morocco<br />

will provide useful informati<strong>on</strong> for<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r MPs.<br />

√ Problems related to loss of revenue<br />

and employment suggest an extensi<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong> period required to set up <strong>the</strong><br />

free-trade z<strong>on</strong>e with EU and Morocco<br />

from 3-5 years as was <strong>the</strong> case with<br />

Tunisia, provided that supplementary<br />

measures are taken to increase <strong>the</strong><br />

capacity of <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy to resp<strong>on</strong>d<br />

to liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of exchanges. This<br />

delay will shelter Morocco from additi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

pressures <strong>on</strong> its competitiveness<br />

and will limit lay offs. Tunisia<br />

already obtained a delay and giving it


ano<strong>the</strong>r is not pertinent because this<br />

will encourage firms and government<br />

to postp<strong>on</strong>e restructuring, which is a<br />

necessity to face market realities.<br />

√ Streng<strong>the</strong>ning educati<strong>on</strong> is necessary<br />

for <strong>the</strong> three countries at all levels.<br />

Their reforms should aim firstly at<br />

promoting adaptati<strong>on</strong> capabilities and<br />

flexibility of manpower. That is to say<br />

possessing basic knowledge including<br />

in <strong>the</strong> domain of new technologies.<br />

At <strong>the</strong> level of sec<strong>on</strong>dary and higher<br />

educati<strong>on</strong>, an extensi<strong>on</strong> for professi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

apprenticeship and lifel<strong>on</strong>g learning<br />

would be welcome.<br />

The project to establish a free exchange<br />

z<strong>on</strong>e between <strong>the</strong> EU and MPs flagrantly<br />

lacks a clear-cut ec<strong>on</strong>omic strategy for<br />

countries that need to liberalize. With<br />

time, predicti<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>cerning rising revenues<br />

and employment in partner countries,<br />

that <strong>the</strong>oretically should ensue<br />

from liberalizati<strong>on</strong> and reform of nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic policies, proved to be<br />

overly optimistic. Few studies focused<br />

<strong>on</strong> analyzing <strong>the</strong> nature of competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

that <strong>the</strong>se countries could progressively<br />

come to bear in <strong>the</strong>ir principal<br />

export markets. Given <strong>the</strong> problems<br />

experienced by Morocco and Tunisia<br />

with <strong>the</strong>ir exportati<strong>on</strong> keys, it is urgent<br />

today to elaborate realistic development<br />

strategies. This primarily means that<br />

<strong>the</strong>y must understand that reform and<br />

investment in infrastructure are prerequisites<br />

but were unable to generate <strong>the</strong><br />

dynamism required by <strong>the</strong>se countries.<br />

Hence o<strong>the</strong>r ways and means must be<br />

devised. According to <strong>the</strong> team who<br />

undertook this study, <strong>the</strong>se strategies<br />

should bear in mind <strong>the</strong> specificities of<br />

<strong>the</strong>se countries in order to identify and<br />

exploit new export opportunities while<br />

-45-<br />

exploring possibilities of enhancing <strong>the</strong><br />

expansi<strong>on</strong> of intensive producti<strong>on</strong> at<br />

work in <strong>the</strong> domestic market. The latter<br />

aspect depends <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> rhythm of expansi<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong> domestic market. Its rise<br />

will augment demand by <strong>the</strong> necessary<br />

proporti<strong>on</strong> but it is difficult to c<strong>on</strong>trol<br />

and it will in turn depend <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> rhythm<br />

of expansi<strong>on</strong> of intensive exportati<strong>on</strong><br />

at work (goods and services). It also<br />

depends <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> EU’s will to c<strong>on</strong>tribute,<br />

for example by reducing restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong><br />

horticultural imports from Maghreb. It is<br />

equally necessary to improve quality and<br />

competitiveness of domestic products<br />

and to generate higher revenue for <strong>the</strong><br />

domestic ec<strong>on</strong>omy by acquiring technical<br />

training.<br />

In Morocco where significant but unexploited<br />

capabilities are available in <strong>the</strong><br />

domain of water reserves (Yang and<br />

Zehnder,2002), restructuring of farms via<br />

redirecting cereal producing land which<br />

is irrigated <strong>on</strong> a large scale towards horticulture<br />

units and adding more intensive<br />

animal husbandry can increase revenue<br />

and employment. C<strong>on</strong>sequently, it will<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tribute to <strong>the</strong> expansi<strong>on</strong> of domestic<br />

demand for locally produced goods and<br />

services. Implementati<strong>on</strong> of this strategy<br />

will <strong>on</strong>ly be viable if liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

agricultural imports by EU not <strong>on</strong>ly take<br />

place but does so through a negotiated<br />

process that recognizes <strong>the</strong> rati<strong>on</strong>ale of<br />

a slower transiti<strong>on</strong> toward lifting protecti<strong>on</strong><br />

from agricultural products in <strong>the</strong><br />

Mediterranean.<br />

Whatever <strong>the</strong> case may be, if revitalizati<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong> TC network is necessary, it<br />

also appears to be a short-term objective<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sidering <strong>the</strong> less<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>the</strong> first<br />

two chapters. It is a more global strategy<br />

of sectoral diversificati<strong>on</strong> as well as


<strong>on</strong>e lending support to local enterprises<br />

which should be elaborated. Within a<br />

c<strong>on</strong>text marked by intensive competitiveness<br />

between developing countries<br />

in <strong>the</strong> manufacturing sector and new<br />

openings in <strong>the</strong> market for exportable<br />

services, <strong>the</strong> pertinent questi<strong>on</strong> according<br />

to <strong>Femise</strong> is to improve capacities<br />

for resp<strong>on</strong>ding to supply from MPs and<br />

<strong>the</strong> emergence of sectors that could<br />

take over present specializati<strong>on</strong>s that no<br />

l<strong>on</strong>ger keep pace with <strong>the</strong> most dynamic<br />

markets in <strong>the</strong> world. As indicated<br />

by surveys <strong>on</strong> enterprises in part 1, in<br />

order to carry this out, any industrial<br />

strategy should be coherent with <strong>the</strong><br />

points raised in <strong>the</strong> first part <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

needs of enterprises which, in <strong>the</strong> first<br />

place, have essentially stressed <strong>the</strong> particular<br />

importance of <strong>the</strong> services sector,<br />

namely financial, communicati<strong>on</strong>s, and<br />

transport services.<br />

4. Services, relay opportunities<br />

Services are seldom tackled by development<br />

<strong>the</strong>ories which, marked as <strong>the</strong>y<br />

are by industrial traditi<strong>on</strong>, are c<strong>on</strong>fined<br />

to <strong>the</strong> role of supports for industry.<br />

However, current technical and instituti<strong>on</strong>al<br />

evoluti<strong>on</strong> demands a re-evaluati<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong> viability of development by services.<br />

Progress in telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s and<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> modifies <strong>the</strong> divisi<strong>on</strong> of work<br />

and creates new possibilities for externalizati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

delocalizati<strong>on</strong> and exportati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

services activities. Simultaneously, accumulati<strong>on</strong><br />

of human capital in developing<br />

countries allows some to mobilize a<br />

supply of qualified and competitive manpower<br />

for such productive activities.<br />

In a c<strong>on</strong>text marked by insufficient statistical<br />

coverage and a problematic that<br />

is relatively new, several approaches are<br />

-46-<br />

combined. After a syn<strong>the</strong>sis of <strong>the</strong> tertiarisati<strong>on</strong><br />

process in different MPs and<br />

exportati<strong>on</strong> prospects in this domain,<br />

<strong>on</strong>e can deal with <strong>the</strong> opportunities that<br />

are being opened before MPs today,<br />

ei<strong>the</strong>r by developing comparative advantages<br />

and promising niches (tourism,<br />

health services) or by liberalizing and<br />

reforming sectors identified in <strong>the</strong> first<br />

part as indispensable in assisting firms<br />

to adapt to <strong>the</strong> new c<strong>on</strong>text (banking<br />

services, telecom, transport).<br />

Growth and development perspectives<br />

for services in <strong>the</strong><br />

Mediterranean<br />

The process of tertiarizati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerns<br />

rich and developing countries alike and<br />

<strong>the</strong> correlati<strong>on</strong> between income per capita<br />

and degree of tertiarizati<strong>on</strong> is narrow.<br />

Turkey aside, MPs are an excepti<strong>on</strong> to<br />

<strong>the</strong>se heavy structural trends, <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>on</strong>e hand because at <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>al level,<br />

<strong>the</strong>re is no relati<strong>on</strong> between per capita<br />

GDP and c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of services to GDP.<br />

On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, at <strong>the</strong> level of nati<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omies,<br />

<strong>the</strong> weight of services stagnates<br />

(Jordan, Morocco, Tunisia) or diminishes<br />

(Algeria, Syria) since <strong>the</strong> 1970s.<br />

However, <strong>on</strong>going internati<strong>on</strong>alizati<strong>on</strong> in<br />

<strong>the</strong> service ec<strong>on</strong>omy seems to have<br />

started quite early <strong>on</strong> in MPs. The opening<br />

rate of services, in <strong>the</strong> aggregate,<br />

is higher than <strong>the</strong> world or European<br />

average; and it is rising. As for all MPs,<br />

<strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of exported services<br />

to nati<strong>on</strong>al income increased by 50%<br />

during <strong>the</strong> past two decades. This sector<br />

accounts for a larger share than o<strong>the</strong>rs<br />

in total exports. It provides more than<br />

half of export revenues in two countries<br />

(Egypt, Leban<strong>on</strong>), and more than <strong>on</strong>e<br />

quarter in five o<strong>the</strong>rs (Turkey, Israel,


Morocco, Tunisia, Jordan). At <strong>the</strong> regio-<br />

nal level, exchange of services generates<br />

a growing trade surplus and c<strong>on</strong>stitutes<br />

an essential factor in stabilizing <strong>the</strong><br />

balance of payments. Despite this “specializati<strong>on</strong><br />

of services”, MPs have not<br />

profited from <strong>the</strong> internati<strong>on</strong>alizati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong> sector as much as o<strong>the</strong>r developing<br />

countries and <strong>the</strong>ir share in <strong>the</strong> global<br />

market has fallen. Never<strong>the</strong>less, MPs<br />

are characterized by a marked heterogeneity<br />

in terms of different indicators<br />

of trade performance. Utilizati<strong>on</strong> of a<br />

classificati<strong>on</strong> breakdown in ten branches<br />

of services will allow a descripti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

service specializati<strong>on</strong>s in each MP and<br />

identify, al<strong>on</strong>gside <strong>the</strong> effective specializati<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

existing growth opportunities<br />

(table x14).<br />

Gains of liberalizati<strong>on</strong> in services:<br />

<strong>the</strong> case of banks and telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Besides traditi<strong>on</strong>al markets such as tourism<br />

(illustrated opposite) or nascent<br />

such as exchanges in health services<br />

(illustrated below), <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r side of <strong>the</strong><br />

-47-<br />

Box: Exportati<strong>on</strong> of tourism services in<br />

Tunisia and Mediterranean countries<br />

Tourism c<strong>on</strong>stitutes <strong>on</strong>e third of global services<br />

exports. As for MPs, revenues from <strong>the</strong> item<br />

travel rose to 20 billi<strong>on</strong> US dollars in 2000, as<br />

compared to 10 billi<strong>on</strong> for textile exports, 90<br />

billi<strong>on</strong> for total goods exported and 5 billi<strong>on</strong><br />

derived from emigrati<strong>on</strong>. These revenues provide<br />

between 15% (Turkey) and 50% (Cyprus) of<br />

incoming hard currencies. Direct net revenues<br />

from tourism represent a growing percentage<br />

of GDP in <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>: from 1 point in 1980 to<br />

4 points in 2000. For MPs who posses <strong>the</strong>se,<br />

<strong>the</strong> utilizati<strong>on</strong> of satellite accounts of tourism<br />

dem<strong>on</strong>strate that <strong>the</strong> sector’s weight measured<br />

by <strong>the</strong> demand of <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy, ranges from<br />

10% (Turkey) to 19% (Tunisia). The place it<br />

occupies in employment is close to its participati<strong>on</strong><br />

in GDP. The link between added-value<br />

and tourism employment (excluding induced<br />

effect) leads to a producti<strong>on</strong> level similar to TC<br />

activity.<br />

The Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Mediterranean is <strong>on</strong>e of <strong>the</strong> prime<br />

destinati<strong>on</strong>s for mass tourism. The flux into <strong>the</strong><br />

regi<strong>on</strong> rose from 4% (1990) to 6% (2003) of<br />

global tourism, whereas income was multiplied<br />

by 2.5. Simultaneously, competitiveness was<br />

intensified <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> Euro-Mediterranean market.<br />

However, tourism offers by MPs vary far more<br />

than at first glance. Indeed <strong>on</strong>e can observe<br />

nati<strong>on</strong>al preferences which are translated by distinct<br />

specializati<strong>on</strong>s, sometimes by <strong>the</strong> sending<br />

country or by <strong>the</strong> receiving country. Moreover,<br />

exportati<strong>on</strong> performance is equally diverse. It<br />

is possible to distinguish three diverse profiles:<br />

extensive growth (Turkey), intensive growth<br />

(Morocco), loss of competiti<strong>on</strong> (Egypt, Tunisia).<br />

Table X14: tax<strong>on</strong>omy of service industries for which <strong>the</strong>re is a potential growth<br />

Industry<br />

Services<br />

Turkey Israel Algeria Morocco Tunisie Egypt Jordan Leban<strong>on</strong> Syria<br />

Commercial Services ..<br />

Services Transport + .. ..<br />

Maritime Transport + .. .. ..<br />

Air Transport .. + .. ..<br />

O<strong>the</strong>rs transports .. + .. ..<br />

Traveling + .. + + .. +<br />

O<strong>the</strong>rs Services ..<br />

Communicati<strong>on</strong>s .. .. + .. .. ..<br />

C<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> + .. + + .. .. ..<br />

Insurance .. .. .. ..<br />

Financial Services .. .. .. .. .. ..<br />

Computer Services .. .. .. .. + + .. .. ..<br />

Royalties and licences revenues .. .. .. .. ..<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r Business services + .. ..<br />

Pers. Serv., Cult & entertainment + .. .. .. + .. .. ..<br />

Governmental Services, n.i.e. ..<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong>, study FEM22-34<br />

.. no informati<strong>on</strong> available<br />

+ Services with growth potential<br />

Services in which <strong>the</strong> country is specialised


Box: Internati<strong>on</strong>al trade health services<br />

and exportati<strong>on</strong> perspectives<br />

of developing countries<br />

Exportati<strong>on</strong> of health services traditi<strong>on</strong>ally<br />

flowed from North to South; patients<br />

traveled inversely. However, factors that<br />

ensured <strong>the</strong> attracti<strong>on</strong> of health services<br />

in <strong>the</strong> North progressively became comm<strong>on</strong>place<br />

and widespread al<strong>on</strong>g with <strong>the</strong><br />

increase and improvement of medical<br />

capabilities in several developing countries.<br />

Export opportunities in this sector are<br />

evaluated here, <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>e hand by<br />

estimating <strong>the</strong> volume of internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

health trade in terms of trends and<br />

structure of <strong>the</strong>se exchanges. On <strong>the</strong><br />

o<strong>the</strong>r, by analyzing <strong>the</strong> Tunisian experience.<br />

Exportati<strong>on</strong> of health services<br />

represents <strong>on</strong>e quarter of private sector<br />

activity. With <strong>the</strong> accommodati<strong>on</strong> services<br />

involved, <strong>the</strong>y attained 107 milli<strong>on</strong><br />

US dollars in 2003 – nearly 4% of<br />

Tunisian service exports– and provided<br />

nearly 10 500 jobs.<br />

At <strong>the</strong> global level, this trade witnesses<br />

an expansi<strong>on</strong> that is faster than <strong>the</strong> average<br />

of <strong>the</strong> exchanges, especially since<br />

2000. It stood at 11.8 billi<strong>on</strong> US dollars<br />

in 2003, that is 0.75% of global services<br />

exchanges. This proporti<strong>on</strong> has doubled<br />

since 1997. Case studies and global analysis<br />

c<strong>on</strong>verge to underline <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

dimensi<strong>on</strong> of external health services.<br />

84% foreign patients in Tunisia, 87%<br />

in Jordan hail from neighbouring countries.<br />

Trade of o<strong>the</strong>r developing countries’<br />

exporters of health care (Thailand,<br />

Malaysia, Cuba) is subject to <strong>the</strong> same<br />

principle of proximity. The particular<br />

nature of trade in health services and<br />

<strong>the</strong> specificity of its demand explain this<br />

predominance in South-South exchanges.<br />

These two characteristics highlight<br />

a promising niche for MPs in <strong>the</strong> Euro-<br />

Mediterranean in <strong>the</strong> vicinity of <strong>the</strong><br />

EU, but also prospects of expansi<strong>on</strong> in<br />

South-South integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

-48-<br />

questi<strong>on</strong> of services could be appre-<br />

hended in terms of competitiveness.<br />

As been underlined <strong>on</strong> many instances,<br />

MPs have committed to an opening up<br />

strategy. But, this for <strong>the</strong> time being is<br />

focused <strong>on</strong> industrial sectors. It is <strong>the</strong>refore<br />

necessary to advance <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> questi<strong>on</strong><br />

of services, rapidly in certain key<br />

sectors well identified through <strong>the</strong> reacti<strong>on</strong><br />

of firms (cf. part 1), for two reas<strong>on</strong>s<br />

that reinforce <strong>on</strong>e ano<strong>the</strong>r: (i) to identify<br />

new specializati<strong>on</strong>s that would augur<br />

well as <strong>the</strong> world evolves; (ii) to foster<br />

c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s that favour competitiveness<br />

of local companies so that <strong>the</strong>y can keep<br />

pace with o<strong>the</strong>r sectors.<br />

Certainly today <strong>the</strong>re is recogniti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong> importance of services in <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy.<br />

Technological progress also plays<br />

a key role in <strong>the</strong> attenti<strong>on</strong> given to trade<br />

in services by decisi<strong>on</strong> makers. Progress<br />

in <strong>the</strong> fields of finance, informati<strong>on</strong> technology,<br />

communicati<strong>on</strong>s, and transport<br />

has c<strong>on</strong>tributed to a rapid expansi<strong>on</strong><br />

of trade in services. L<strong>on</strong>g c<strong>on</strong>sidered<br />

as expensive, internati<strong>on</strong>al transacti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

have been facilitated by <strong>the</strong> flow of electr<strong>on</strong>ic<br />

informati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The advantages of liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of services<br />

were highlighted by certain facts,<br />

such as <strong>the</strong> increase in exports and FDI<br />

achieved by countries which have enhanced<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir services performance related<br />

to trade (transport, finance, roads and<br />

telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s).<br />

Internal reforms aim at lowering <strong>the</strong><br />

cost of transport and daily management<br />

of affairs can play a crucial role<br />

in improving access to global markets.<br />

Liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of services will streng<strong>the</strong>n<br />

<strong>the</strong> capability of exporters to resp<strong>on</strong>d to<br />

reforms carried out within <strong>the</strong> framework<br />

of trade, and allow local producers to


etter coordinate <strong>the</strong>ir activities with<br />

input suppliers situated in higher income<br />

countries, <strong>the</strong>reby rendering <strong>the</strong> country<br />

more attractive for FDI. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore,<br />

liberalizing trade in services can create<br />

investment opportunities for <strong>the</strong> private<br />

domestic sector and help in drawing<br />

foreign investments that do not entail<br />

a debt burden such as FDI and portfolio<br />

investments. FDI in services was<br />

<strong>the</strong> principal engine of FDI global flux<br />

during <strong>the</strong> 1990s and today represents<br />

nearly half of <strong>the</strong> value of FDI stock in<br />

<strong>the</strong> world.<br />

However, MPs experience difficulties<br />

of profiting from <strong>the</strong>se global trends<br />

because <strong>the</strong>y are inclined to implement<br />

services reforms in a dislocated<br />

manner. Privatizati<strong>on</strong>s that took place<br />

were slower than in o<strong>the</strong>r parts of <strong>the</strong><br />

world; barriers up<strong>on</strong> entry always held<br />

back investors both foreign and local.<br />

The reas<strong>on</strong> for this is undoubtedly to be<br />

found in strategies to preserve employment.<br />

Services, essentially public, were<br />

(and still are) envisaged in <strong>the</strong> first place<br />

as a reservoir for employment which<br />

eventually allow <strong>the</strong> management of<br />

social adjustment in industry. They are<br />

not understood as “productive” sectors<br />

in <strong>the</strong>mselves. Therefore, what undeniably<br />

emerges from surveys c<strong>on</strong>ducted by<br />

<strong>Femise</strong> teams is that a number of <strong>the</strong>se<br />

sectors participated in <strong>the</strong> industrial<br />

process, providing firms with o<strong>the</strong>r competitive<br />

sources, <strong>the</strong>reby placing <strong>the</strong>m in<br />

<strong>the</strong> heart of <strong>the</strong> industrial processes. The<br />

specificity of MPs according to this point<br />

of view is that <strong>the</strong>y act negatively, that<br />

is to say firms regret <strong>the</strong>ir absence and<br />

inefficiency. Hence, not <strong>on</strong>ly can <strong>the</strong>y<br />

evolve as a new regi<strong>on</strong>al specializati<strong>on</strong><br />

but <strong>the</strong> effects practicing <strong>on</strong> local fabrics<br />

can lead to better returns <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir open<br />

-49-<br />

door strategy in general, and <strong>the</strong> Euro-<br />

Mediterranean process in particular.<br />

Opening up of services markets in <strong>the</strong><br />

Mediterranean regi<strong>on</strong> to competiti<strong>on</strong> can<br />

offset <strong>the</strong> costs of adjustment stemming<br />

from merchandise trade liberalizati<strong>on</strong>:<br />

pro-competitive reforms that facilitate<br />

entry by new firms can generate large<br />

employment opportunities for skilled and<br />

unskilled workers who are employed by<br />

governments in low productivity jobs.<br />

Because services often cannot be traded,<br />

increasing access to services markets<br />

is likely to entail <strong>the</strong> entry of foreign<br />

competitors through FDI. This will lead<br />

to <strong>the</strong> introducti<strong>on</strong> of new technologies<br />

as well as hiring domestic labor.<br />

In this secti<strong>on</strong>, based <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> case of<br />

four Mediterranean partner countries<br />

(Egypt, Morocco, Tunisia, and Turkey),<br />

we are going to explore <strong>the</strong> potential<br />

welfare gains of <strong>the</strong> liberalizati<strong>on</strong>, more<br />

specifically defined as alignment with<br />

EU regulati<strong>on</strong>s of trade in services, in<br />

three sectors: <strong>the</strong> banking sector, <strong>the</strong><br />

telecommunicati<strong>on</strong> sector and <strong>the</strong> maritime<br />

transport sector. Special emphasis<br />

is drawn <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> banking sector, where<br />

highlights of recent reforms and recent<br />

performance of <strong>the</strong> sector in <strong>the</strong> respective<br />

countries is given, and <strong>on</strong> transport<br />

due to <strong>the</strong> expected gain and <strong>the</strong> coherence<br />

with <strong>the</strong> MP strategies. For <strong>the</strong><br />

3 sectors, <strong>the</strong> general presentati<strong>on</strong> is<br />

followed by an estimati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> overall<br />

welfare gains of liberalizati<strong>on</strong> through<br />

compliance with EU regulati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Banking sector: Effects of full c<strong>on</strong>formity<br />

with EU<br />

During <strong>the</strong> nineties, several MENA<br />

countries have embarked <strong>on</strong> significant


eform programs of <strong>the</strong>ir financial sec-<br />

tors, where <strong>the</strong>y comm<strong>on</strong>ly initiated<br />

with banking sector reform. The outcomes<br />

of those programs, though varied<br />

across countries, were generally modest<br />

and have thus urged for ano<strong>the</strong>r wave<br />

of reform and modernizati<strong>on</strong>. Within <strong>the</strong><br />

phase to come, most MENA ec<strong>on</strong>omies<br />

will be looking forward to setting <strong>the</strong><br />

stage for deeper global integrati<strong>on</strong>, of<br />

which integrati<strong>on</strong> with <strong>the</strong> EU is a key<br />

ingredient. Thus, several countries of<br />

<strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong> are indeed c<strong>on</strong>sidering opening<br />

up <strong>the</strong>ir services sectors gradually<br />

to <strong>the</strong> EU competiti<strong>on</strong>; that is to extend<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir Free Trade Agreement with <strong>the</strong> EU<br />

to cover trade in services.<br />

It is worth noting that liberalizati<strong>on</strong> as<br />

used in this c<strong>on</strong>text is not meant to<br />

denote <strong>the</strong> removal of all regulati<strong>on</strong>s or<br />

all forms of restricti<strong>on</strong>s, but it refers to<br />

<strong>the</strong> status where prudential regulati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

essential for <strong>the</strong> survival of <strong>the</strong> banking<br />

sector is preserved. Thus, <strong>the</strong> term<br />

“liberalizati<strong>on</strong>” in this secti<strong>on</strong> refers to<br />

<strong>the</strong> alignment of countries’ legislati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

and instituti<strong>on</strong>s with those comm<strong>on</strong>ly<br />

adopted by <strong>the</strong> EU countries, and hence<br />

also refers to <strong>the</strong> compliance to <strong>the</strong><br />

requirements of integrati<strong>on</strong> with <strong>the</strong> EU.<br />

This part basically explores <strong>the</strong> impact<br />

of <strong>the</strong> liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> banking sectors<br />

in four selected MENA countries<br />

(Egypt, Tunisia, Morocco, and Turkey) <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong>ir performance, while assuming <strong>the</strong><br />

country undertakes <strong>the</strong> reforms needed<br />

for a successful integrati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Opening banking services to <strong>the</strong> EU competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

may arguably lead to <strong>the</strong> improvement<br />

of <strong>the</strong> banking system in <strong>the</strong><br />

MENA countries, paving <strong>the</strong> way for better<br />

and cheaper services. As compared<br />

to <strong>the</strong> case of trade in goods, measuring<br />

-50-<br />

liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of trade in services is found<br />

to be difficult and problematic. Trade in<br />

services differs from trade in goods, not<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly for being applied <strong>on</strong> four c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al<br />

modes, but also because of <strong>the</strong> way<br />

<strong>the</strong> domestic market is protected. In<br />

case of services, a country’s legislati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

and instituti<strong>on</strong>s are assumed to add to<br />

mere tariff protecti<strong>on</strong> observed in <strong>the</strong><br />

case of goods. However, it has been possible<br />

to calculate tariff equivalent to <strong>the</strong><br />

restrictive regulati<strong>on</strong>. This facilitates <strong>the</strong><br />

estimati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> impact of liberalizati<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>on</strong> various indicators, including prices<br />

and welfare.<br />

This secti<strong>on</strong>, based <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> result of a<br />

<strong>Femise</strong> study[28], will provide for <strong>the</strong><br />

estimati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> overall welfare benefits<br />

accruing from <strong>the</strong> implementati<strong>on</strong> of full<br />

liberalizati<strong>on</strong> measures, by quantifying<br />

<strong>the</strong> tariff equivalent of restrictive measures<br />

adopted in <strong>the</strong> banking sector and<br />

testing <strong>the</strong> effect of lifting <strong>the</strong>m.<br />

In Egypt, <strong>the</strong> liberalizati<strong>on</strong> moves were<br />

translated into a sector enjoying a relatively<br />

low tariff equivalent rate (11.7%)<br />

compared to 5% in <strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong> EU.<br />

A number of additi<strong>on</strong>al indicators, not<br />

included in <strong>the</strong> calculati<strong>on</strong>s, if taken<br />

into c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> would have even<br />

resulted in a lower tariff equivalent. The<br />

simulati<strong>on</strong>s showed that if <strong>the</strong> banking<br />

sector in Egypt was more liberalized<br />

reaching <strong>the</strong> extent of liberalizati<strong>on</strong> in<br />

<strong>the</strong> EU this would not be translated<br />

into significant welfare gains for <strong>the</strong><br />

Egyptian ec<strong>on</strong>omy where a 6% reducti<strong>on</strong><br />

of prices will result <strong>on</strong>ly in 1.44%<br />

welfare gains in c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> and 1.2%<br />

of GDP. Moreover, even if larger price<br />

cuts were undertaken it will not result<br />

into larger welfare gains where a 26%<br />

price reducti<strong>on</strong> will increase <strong>the</strong> welfare


gains to 6.54% of c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> and<br />

5.47% of GDP.<br />

In Tunisia, <strong>the</strong> result obtained gives a<br />

rate of restrictiveness (RI) of 55 percent;<br />

which is quite remarkable: this<br />

rate is high but comparable to o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

results obtained for o<strong>the</strong>r similar developing<br />

countries. It implies, approximately,<br />

a 50 percent tariff equivalent rate.<br />

Using <strong>the</strong> 1997 Tunisian 99 sector inputoutput<br />

table, <strong>the</strong> calculati<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>the</strong> price<br />

and welfare variati<strong>on</strong>s were performed,<br />

it comes out that <strong>the</strong> gains are positive,<br />

significant but modest. Prices, o<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

<strong>the</strong> banking price, would decrease by no<br />

more than1 percent and often by less<br />

than 0.5%. And <strong>the</strong> total welfare gain is<br />

less than 0.5 % of <strong>the</strong> current GDP.<br />

As for Morocco, harm<strong>on</strong>izing <strong>the</strong> Moroccan<br />

banking sector regulati<strong>on</strong>s al<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> EU<br />

lines, would translate into a reducti<strong>on</strong><br />

of 19.3 percent of <strong>the</strong> cost of banking<br />

services, given that <strong>the</strong> restrictiveness<br />

index for <strong>the</strong> EU is estimated at 0.0708,<br />

which leads to a tariff equivalent of 6.3<br />

percent in comparis<strong>on</strong> with a scenario<br />

of full liberalizati<strong>on</strong>. In order to assess<br />

<strong>the</strong> effect of this reducti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy,<br />

<strong>the</strong> 1998 Input-Output table of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Moroccan ec<strong>on</strong>omy has been used<br />

assuming that <strong>the</strong>re are no significant<br />

changes in <strong>the</strong> structure of <strong>the</strong> Moroccan<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omy over <strong>the</strong> period 1998-<strong>2005</strong>.<br />

The results indicate that <strong>the</strong> welfare,<br />

captured through total c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>, will<br />

improve by 1.15 percent. Since in 1998<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> represented 86.12 percent<br />

of GDP, this welfare gain will translate<br />

into an increase of 0.9912 percent in<br />

GDP.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> Turkish case, with <strong>the</strong> new price of<br />

banking services under liberalizati<strong>on</strong>, it<br />

-51-<br />

was found that <strong>the</strong> welfare of <strong>the</strong> society<br />

will increase by 1.38 percent. Thus, <strong>the</strong><br />

effect of <strong>the</strong> adopti<strong>on</strong> of EU rules and<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong>s similar to those of <strong>the</strong> EU<br />

countries in <strong>the</strong> banking sector amounts<br />

to US$ 2.1 billi<strong>on</strong> annual increase in <strong>the</strong><br />

real income of <strong>the</strong> Turkish c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

Since during 1996 c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> formed<br />

72.95 percent of GDP, <strong>the</strong> percentage<br />

change in welfare of <strong>the</strong> society is equivalent<br />

to 1 percent increase in real GDP.<br />

Moreover, as <strong>the</strong> cost of <strong>the</strong> 2001 financial<br />

crisis has been estimated as $53.2<br />

billi<strong>on</strong>, and c<strong>on</strong>sidering <strong>the</strong> figure of<br />

6.86 percent for <strong>the</strong> annual real interest<br />

rate, we note that <strong>the</strong> annual cost of<br />

<strong>the</strong> currency crisis amounts to US$ 3.65<br />

billi<strong>on</strong>. Turkey would not have incurred<br />

this cost if it had adopted and implemented<br />

<strong>the</strong> legislative, regulatory, and instituti<strong>on</strong>al<br />

framework of <strong>the</strong> EU banking<br />

system at <strong>the</strong> beginning of <strong>the</strong> 1990’s.<br />

Noting that GDP in 2004 has amounted<br />

to US$ 300.63 billi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> welfare gain<br />

from adopting <strong>the</strong> EU rules and regulati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

in <strong>the</strong> banking sector can be thus<br />

calculated as 2.2 percent of GDP.<br />

It can be inferred from previous results<br />

that adopting EU regulati<strong>on</strong>s is not<br />

expected to result in a significant boost<br />

in <strong>the</strong> overall welfare. The highest potential<br />

gains were observed in Egypt (1.2%<br />

of GDP), and <strong>the</strong> lowest were observed<br />

in Tunisia (0.5%). However, this abstracts<br />

from <strong>the</strong> even more important<br />

gain produced by a more competitive<br />

banking sector, <strong>the</strong> effect <strong>on</strong> investment<br />

and growth, which is not captured by <strong>the</strong><br />

input-output equati<strong>on</strong>s. The quantitative<br />

exercise, however, points here <strong>on</strong>ly to<br />

<strong>the</strong> fixed effects of prices, which are<br />

positive, and generally nearly <strong>on</strong>e point<br />

of GDP, bearing in mind that <strong>the</strong>se effects<br />

are calculated using input-output table,


which assumes a c<strong>on</strong>stant of productive<br />

combinati<strong>on</strong>s. As explained previously,<br />

<strong>the</strong> essential gain expected from a “mise<br />

à niveau” of <strong>the</strong> banking sector, rests<br />

in fact, <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> dynamic effects that will<br />

result from <strong>the</strong> positive modificati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong> firm’s competitiveness (we need to<br />

remember that most of <strong>the</strong> studies that<br />

were based <strong>on</strong> analyzing impediments<br />

facing firms, recognized <strong>the</strong> access to<br />

financing as <strong>the</strong> main c<strong>on</strong>cern) <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

whole sectors.<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r much underestimated effect is <strong>the</strong><br />

anticipati<strong>on</strong>s effect, which is going to<br />

bring, at a given moment, <strong>the</strong> society<br />

to take a decisive step. The example of<br />

<strong>the</strong> textile and clothing sector, and its<br />

under-investment, also indicates that<br />

<strong>the</strong> current agents` expectati<strong>on</strong>s are<br />

reserved to <strong>the</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>al level. Therefore,<br />

<strong>the</strong> modificati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> banking sector,<br />

in particular in its functi<strong>on</strong> as provider<br />

of financial resources to enterprises, will<br />

c<strong>on</strong>stitute a decisive stage, firstly by<br />

bringing a visible change in <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

of <strong>the</strong> agents’ daily operati<strong>on</strong>s with<br />

a str<strong>on</strong>g symbolic power, and also <strong>the</strong><br />

efficient firms will find means of competitiveness<br />

that are currently lacking.<br />

Liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of telecommunicati<strong>on</strong><br />

Over <strong>the</strong> last decade, <strong>the</strong> telecommunicati<strong>on</strong><br />

sector has embarked <strong>on</strong> a period<br />

of deep change initiated by technological<br />

innovati<strong>on</strong>, liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

markets, and by partial or full liberalizati<strong>on</strong><br />

of incumbent operators. Historically,<br />

telecom operators were state-owned<br />

and vertically integrated m<strong>on</strong>opolists.<br />

Due to large fixed costs of building a<br />

network, <strong>the</strong> activity of providing telecommunicati<strong>on</strong><br />

services was c<strong>on</strong>sidered<br />

as natural m<strong>on</strong>opoly. However, techno-<br />

-52-<br />

logical progress and innovati<strong>on</strong> generated<br />

new transmissi<strong>on</strong> systems and<br />

decreased <strong>the</strong> cost of building infrastructure.<br />

Therefore, <strong>the</strong> idea of a natural<br />

m<strong>on</strong>opoly is no l<strong>on</strong>ger seen as valid.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, evidence indicates that <strong>the</strong><br />

absence of competiti<strong>on</strong> does not provide<br />

incentives to decrease costs, and leads<br />

to inefficiencies and welfare loss. As a<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequence, most historical operators,<br />

all over <strong>the</strong> world, have been subjected<br />

to privatizati<strong>on</strong> plans.<br />

This secti<strong>on</strong> follows <strong>the</strong> same approach<br />

of <strong>the</strong> previous secti<strong>on</strong> in providing<br />

an estimati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> expected welfare<br />

accruing from <strong>the</strong> liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

telecommunicati<strong>on</strong> services in Egypt,<br />

Tunisia, Morocco, and Turkey.<br />

In Egypt, this sector has gained increased<br />

importance since 1999 with <strong>the</strong> establishment<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Ministry of Communicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

and Informati<strong>on</strong> Technology (MCIT). A<br />

number of major changes have happened<br />

in this sector reflecting <strong>the</strong> increasing<br />

role it plays in <strong>the</strong> development process<br />

and in catching up with <strong>the</strong> advanced<br />

technology. The telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

sector c<strong>on</strong>tributes largely to <strong>the</strong> Gross<br />

Domestic Product (GDP) where <strong>the</strong> official<br />

statistics show that it represents<br />

3%. Moreover, it is c<strong>on</strong>sidered <strong>on</strong>e of <strong>the</strong><br />

fastest growing sectors in <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy.<br />

The number of employees in <strong>the</strong> whole<br />

sector was estimated at around 0.27% of<br />

<strong>the</strong> total labour force, which is relatively<br />

low revealing <strong>the</strong> capital intensive nature<br />

of this industry. The sector had seen<br />

a total expenditure of 2.3 billi<strong>on</strong> US dollars<br />

in 2001 which represented 2.5% of<br />

GDP (Internati<strong>on</strong>al Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Uni<strong>on</strong> (ITU), 2001). The FR index for<br />

<strong>the</strong> fixed line was 0.519 and <strong>the</strong> Foreign<br />

Discriminatory Restrictiveness (FDR)


was 0.387 which represents around 75%<br />

of <strong>the</strong> FR. The same exercise was repeated<br />

assuming <strong>the</strong> more liberal scenario<br />

likely to prevail after <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>2005</strong>. An<br />

FR index of 0.138 and an FDR index of<br />

0.0973 were obtained, where <strong>the</strong> latter<br />

represents around 70% of <strong>the</strong> FR index.<br />

For <strong>the</strong> mobile subsector we obtained<br />

an FR index of 0.354 and FDR index of<br />

0.235 which represents 67% of <strong>the</strong> FR.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> internet sub sector we obtained<br />

an FR index of 0.124 and FDR of 0.089<br />

which represents 72% of <strong>the</strong> FR.<br />

On calculating <strong>the</strong> tariff equivalent <strong>the</strong><br />

results obtained were 13% in <strong>the</strong> case<br />

of <strong>the</strong> mobile which decreases to 4%<br />

if <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>stant of <strong>the</strong> fixed line sector<br />

is applied instead of <strong>the</strong> mobile. In <strong>the</strong><br />

case of <strong>the</strong> internet, where <strong>the</strong> fixed line<br />

coefficients were applied, a tariff equivalent<br />

of 2% was obtained.<br />

Results generally reveal that <strong>the</strong> telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

sector in Egypt has<br />

experienced several changes <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

policy and regulatory level driving <strong>the</strong><br />

sector with all its subsectors towards<br />

liberalizati<strong>on</strong>. The estimated tariff equivalents<br />

showed that <strong>the</strong> mobile sector is<br />

relatively highly protected when compared<br />

with <strong>the</strong> fixed line and <strong>the</strong> internet.<br />

Though this might come as a surprise as<br />

<strong>the</strong> fixed line is likely to be more protective,<br />

it is believed that this is ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

a result of <strong>the</strong> specificati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> model<br />

used (which changes tremendously <strong>the</strong><br />

fixed line model specificati<strong>on</strong> applied).<br />

The estimati<strong>on</strong>s showed that <strong>the</strong>re is<br />

a high expected decrease in <strong>the</strong> level<br />

of protecti<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> case of fixed line<br />

subsector when <strong>the</strong> GATS commitments<br />

are fully implemented by <strong>the</strong> end of<br />

<strong>2005</strong>. Despite <strong>the</strong> rapid adopti<strong>on</strong> of new<br />

technologies and <strong>the</strong> introducti<strong>on</strong> of IT<br />

-53-<br />

in different sectors of <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy, as<br />

observed by different indicators, Egypt is<br />

still relatively lagging when compared to<br />

<strong>the</strong> lower middle income set of countries<br />

to which it bel<strong>on</strong>gs.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> case of Tunisia, <strong>the</strong> Tunisian<br />

government was for a l<strong>on</strong>g time reluctant<br />

before undertaking any strategic<br />

liberalizati<strong>on</strong> move, and little was d<strong>on</strong>e<br />

until 2001. But in 2001, <strong>the</strong> liberalizati<strong>on</strong><br />

process in this sector was accelerated,<br />

and <strong>the</strong> issue is no l<strong>on</strong>ger whe<strong>the</strong>r or not<br />

to open it to competiti<strong>on</strong> and to foreign<br />

investment but how and how fast to liberalize.<br />

The answer should depend <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

expected impact of this liberalizati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> telecommunicati<strong>on</strong> sector itself and<br />

<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> whole ec<strong>on</strong>omy, and also <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

way liberalizati<strong>on</strong> is designed.<br />

Applying <strong>the</strong> analysis separately to fixed<br />

line teleph<strong>on</strong>y, mobiles and internet services,<br />

RI equivalent to 60 percent for<br />

fixed lines, 46 percent for mobiles and<br />

53 percent for <strong>the</strong> internet was obtained...<br />

The sector overall RI is taken as<br />

<strong>the</strong> average of <strong>the</strong> three RIs calculated.<br />

The average overall rate is thus 53 percent.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sequently, <strong>the</strong> overall tariff<br />

equivalent is 70 percent.<br />

The result is not surprising and c<strong>on</strong>firms<br />

that telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s are still<br />

str<strong>on</strong>gly protected. Bey<strong>on</strong>d <strong>the</strong> expected<br />

direct effects for Tunisia however,<br />

<strong>the</strong> main c<strong>on</strong>cern is <strong>the</strong> existence of<br />

coherence within <strong>the</strong> Tunisian strategic<br />

plan of ec<strong>on</strong>omic development based <strong>on</strong><br />

knowledge. Communicati<strong>on</strong>s techniques<br />

are <strong>the</strong> pillar without which <strong>the</strong> success<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Tunisian plan can’t be acheived,<br />

and it requires a huge reducti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

protecti<strong>on</strong>ism in order to increase <strong>the</strong><br />

local diffusi<strong>on</strong>.


As for <strong>the</strong> Moroccan case, Since <strong>the</strong><br />

early nineties, Morocco, like most o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

countries, has put substantial emphasis<br />

<strong>on</strong> telecommunicati<strong>on</strong> and informati<strong>on</strong><br />

technologies. The significant development<br />

recorded over <strong>the</strong> last decade can<br />

be traced back to three major causes:<br />

legal and instituti<strong>on</strong>al telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

reforms; political openness<br />

and democratisati<strong>on</strong>; and, technological<br />

changes.<br />

The overall restrictiveness index for telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

services in Morocco was<br />

estimated to be 0.278, and <strong>the</strong> tariffequivalent<br />

obtained <strong>the</strong>refrom was equivalent<br />

to 32 percent. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong><br />

extent of existing restricti<strong>on</strong>s increases<br />

<strong>the</strong> price of telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s services<br />

by 32 percent compared to what would<br />

prevail under full liberalizati<strong>on</strong>. The calculati<strong>on</strong><br />

also indicates that <strong>the</strong> magnitude<br />

of <strong>the</strong> tariff equivalent amounts<br />

to 40.5 percent for <strong>the</strong> fixed teleph<strong>on</strong>y,<br />

29.7 percent for internet services, and<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly 23.4 percent in <strong>the</strong> mobile teleph<strong>on</strong>y.<br />

These results provide evidence that<br />

full liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

services would benefit users particularly<br />

in fixed teleph<strong>on</strong>y and internet services.<br />

The expected price reducti<strong>on</strong> for mobile<br />

services is relatively lower but still significant<br />

in absolute terms.<br />

In order to assess <strong>the</strong> total effect a 32<br />

percent decrease in <strong>the</strong> price of telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

services <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy,<br />

<strong>the</strong> 1998 Input-Output table of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Moroccan ec<strong>on</strong>omy has been used.<br />

By using this table, it was assumed that<br />

<strong>the</strong>re are no significant changes in <strong>the</strong><br />

structure of <strong>the</strong> Moroccan ec<strong>on</strong>omy over<br />

<strong>the</strong> period 1998-<strong>2005</strong>. In particular, this<br />

presumes that <strong>the</strong> telecommunicati<strong>on</strong><br />

sector plays more or less <strong>the</strong> same role<br />

-54-<br />

in <strong>2005</strong> compared to 1998. Yet, this<br />

assumpti<strong>on</strong> is a serious limitati<strong>on</strong> as it<br />

tends to underestimate <strong>the</strong> remarkable<br />

progress in telecommunicati<strong>on</strong> sector<br />

over <strong>the</strong> last few years. The sec<strong>on</strong>d limitati<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong> 1998 Input-Output table of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Moroccan ec<strong>on</strong>omy is <strong>the</strong> absence<br />

of any distincti<strong>on</strong> between transport<br />

and telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>e line<br />

stands for both. On <strong>the</strong> basis of value<br />

added data, <strong>the</strong> share of telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

in “Transport and telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s”<br />

amounted to 23 percent in 1998<br />

and more than 34 percent in 2002.<br />

On <strong>the</strong> basis of previous computati<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

<strong>the</strong> adopti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> EU rules and regulati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

in <strong>the</strong> telecommunicati<strong>on</strong> sector is<br />

expected to lead to an average reducti<strong>on</strong><br />

of telecom services’ price of 32 percent.<br />

Accordingly, <strong>the</strong> welfare of <strong>the</strong> society<br />

captured through total c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>, will<br />

improve by 1.627 percent. Since in 1998<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> represented 86.12 percent<br />

of GDP, this welfare gain will translate<br />

into an increase of 1.4 percent in GDP.<br />

Since in 2004, GDP amounted to DH<br />

444 billi<strong>on</strong> or <strong>the</strong> equivalent of US$<br />

50 billi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> preliminary and rough<br />

approximati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> welfare gain from<br />

adopting <strong>the</strong> EU rules and regulati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

in <strong>the</strong> telecommunicati<strong>on</strong> sector is estimated<br />

at US$ 700 milli<strong>on</strong>. It very likely<br />

that this figure underestimate <strong>the</strong> total<br />

effect of liberalizing telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

services in Morocco.<br />

In Turkey, <strong>the</strong> telecommunicati<strong>on</strong> services<br />

were provided until 1994 by <strong>the</strong><br />

state owned company PTT, a nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

m<strong>on</strong>opoly providing postal and telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

services. Turkey decided<br />

to liberalize <strong>the</strong> telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

sector during <strong>the</strong> 1990’s. A new


Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Law was passed by<br />

Parliament in 2000, which was amended<br />

in 2001. Since <strong>the</strong>n Turkey is trying to<br />

liberalize <strong>the</strong> telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s sector<br />

by following <strong>the</strong> EU approach to liberalizati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

It recognizes that competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

and regulati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> sector are vital,<br />

and that privatizati<strong>on</strong> combined with<br />

<strong>the</strong> establishment of c<strong>on</strong>duct regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

is essential for achieving ec<strong>on</strong>omic efficiency<br />

and <strong>the</strong> guarantee of a universal<br />

service to keep <strong>the</strong> country away from<br />

<strong>the</strong> danger of digital divide.<br />

Estimati<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>the</strong> FR indexes revealed<br />

a value equals to 0.193 in <strong>the</strong> case of<br />

<strong>the</strong> fixed line, 0.165 in <strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong><br />

mobile, and 0.12 in <strong>the</strong> case of internet<br />

services. Using input-output tables, and<br />

assuming that with <strong>the</strong> adopti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

EU rules and regulati<strong>on</strong>s in <strong>the</strong> telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

sector, telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

price will decrease by 33.53 percent,<br />

<strong>the</strong> welfare of <strong>the</strong> society was found to<br />

increase by 0.587 percent. Thus, <strong>the</strong><br />

effect of <strong>the</strong> adopti<strong>on</strong> of EU rules and<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong>s in <strong>the</strong> telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

sector similar to those of Finland and <strong>the</strong><br />

United Kingdom amounts to US$ 1.12<br />

billi<strong>on</strong> annual increase in <strong>the</strong> real income<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Turkish c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

Since during 1996 c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> formed<br />

72.95 percent of GDP, <strong>the</strong> percentage<br />

change in welfare of <strong>the</strong> society is equivalent<br />

to 0.428 percent increase in real<br />

GDP. Finally, it should be noted that<br />

as of <strong>2005</strong>, Turkey has adopted most<br />

of <strong>the</strong> EU rules and regulati<strong>on</strong>s in <strong>the</strong><br />

telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s sector. With fur<strong>the</strong>r<br />

alignment of <strong>the</strong>se rules and regulati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

to those of <strong>the</strong> EU and strict implementati<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong>se rules and regulati<strong>on</strong>s by<br />

TA, Turkey could derive <strong>the</strong> welfare gains<br />

calculated above.<br />

-55-<br />

The importance of maritime transportati<strong>on</strong><br />

Maritime transportati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>stitutes an<br />

important ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity in almost<br />

all Mediterranean partner countries. For<br />

instance, about 95 percent of internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

trade of goods from and to Tunisia<br />

is shipped, and <strong>the</strong> volume of its trade<br />

(exports and imports) is worth close<br />

to 80 percent of its GDP. In Egypt, <strong>the</strong><br />

importance of <strong>the</strong> sector arises from <strong>the</strong><br />

geographical locati<strong>on</strong> of Egypt which<br />

had made its seaports am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> most<br />

important in <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean area,<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r acting as a hub for <strong>the</strong> Arab<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>, or as an important stati<strong>on</strong> for <strong>the</strong><br />

transshipment cargo between Europe<br />

and <strong>the</strong> rest of <strong>the</strong> world. In Morocco,<br />

available statistics show that more than<br />

98 percent of <strong>the</strong> country’s internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

trade is carried by sea, which is <strong>the</strong> equivalent<br />

of more than 60 milli<strong>on</strong> metric<br />

t<strong>on</strong>s in 2004.<br />

So, transportati<strong>on</strong> is an essential comp<strong>on</strong>ent<br />

of <strong>the</strong> MCs’ capacity to preserve<br />

and extend <strong>the</strong>ir market share and to<br />

face <strong>the</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong>ir markets.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> present case, however, <strong>the</strong> most<br />

important issue is that of <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

coherence, which must be emphasized<br />

while c<strong>on</strong>sidering in details <strong>the</strong> opening<br />

measures, as <strong>the</strong> gains of each country<br />

is dependant <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> acti<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

partners. Thus, if Algeria improves <strong>the</strong><br />

capacity of its airports to accommodate<br />

large cargos, its exchanges can rise with<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r MCs under <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> that <strong>the</strong>y<br />

can offer <strong>the</strong> same services as <strong>the</strong> airline<br />

companies[29].<br />

A <strong>Femise</strong> study <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong> can be referred<br />

to to illustrate <strong>the</strong> importance of <strong>the</strong>


sector[30]. The analysis shows that<br />

trade between z<strong>on</strong>es fur<strong>the</strong>r and fur<strong>the</strong>r<br />

apart has risen thanks to <strong>the</strong><br />

maritime expansi<strong>on</strong> although <strong>the</strong> cost<br />

stays high even despite that it is a<br />

key element of <strong>the</strong> MCs’ capacity to<br />

face <strong>the</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong>. The creati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong> link traffic-quality in infrastructure<br />

seems to be distending itself, this<br />

may appear paradoxical, but, it in fact<br />

reflects <strong>the</strong> existence of scale ec<strong>on</strong>omies.<br />

The countries which were late<br />

in <strong>the</strong> 70s and 80’s have caught up<br />

with <strong>the</strong> most developed countries and<br />

<strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> gains of an additi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

road, for example, will be less and less<br />

significant with <strong>the</strong> extensi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

road network.<br />

Never<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong> traffic creati<strong>on</strong> within<br />

<strong>the</strong> MCs (Algeria, Egypt, Morocco,<br />

Tunisia, Turkey) resulting from a reducti<strong>on</strong><br />

in transportati<strong>on</strong> costs due to an<br />

improvement in transportati<strong>on</strong> quality,<br />

from an intermediary situati<strong>on</strong> to an<br />

equivalent level to that of 25% of <strong>the</strong><br />

most efficient countries[31], could be<br />

between 34% and 55%[32]. Turkey, <strong>the</strong><br />

richest country in <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong> which is<br />

recording a weak share of infrastructure,<br />

could benefit <strong>the</strong> most this way. The<br />

importance is to know if it will get all<br />

potential gains of <strong>the</strong> “mise à niveau”,<br />

Figure 8: Share of each country in <strong>the</strong><br />

z<strong>on</strong>e infrastructures total<br />

Tunisia<br />

Morocco<br />

Source : <strong>Femise</strong> study 22-36<br />

Turkey<br />

Egypt<br />

Algeria<br />

-56-<br />

bearing in mind that <strong>the</strong> necessary<br />

adjustments are c<strong>on</strong>siderable.<br />

Also, <strong>the</strong> global effect of <strong>the</strong> liberalizati<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong> maritime transportati<strong>on</strong><br />

can be calculated, using just about <strong>the</strong><br />

same methodology used in <strong>the</strong> previous<br />

secti<strong>on</strong>s. It summarizes <strong>the</strong> outcome<br />

of a FEMISE study (FEM 22-02) that<br />

investigated <strong>the</strong> overall welfare accruing<br />

from <strong>the</strong> liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> sector to<br />

<strong>the</strong> full compliance with <strong>the</strong> EU regulati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Thus, it should be reiterated that<br />

<strong>the</strong> liberalizati<strong>on</strong> as used in this c<strong>on</strong>text<br />

refers to <strong>the</strong> applicati<strong>on</strong> of EU regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

and does mean <strong>the</strong> abolishment of all<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

The findings in Egypt shows that <strong>the</strong><br />

maritime sector is am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> sectors<br />

that remain relatively restricted when<br />

compared to banking and telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

The tariff equivalents are relatively<br />

high; however it is comparable<br />

with o<strong>the</strong>r countries. In fact <strong>the</strong> Foreign<br />

restrictiveness (FR index) of Egypt is<br />

less than that of <strong>the</strong> United States and<br />

highly comparable with Germany. The<br />

major problem related to <strong>the</strong> maritime<br />

sector is <strong>the</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-transparency where<br />

<strong>the</strong> laws stipulate certain liberal issues,<br />

however reality shows restrictive practices.<br />

Despite <strong>the</strong> reforms undertaken in<br />

<strong>the</strong> 1990s that have helped to liberalize<br />

<strong>the</strong> sector, it still remains highly protected.<br />

This has been c<strong>on</strong>firmed by Egypt’s<br />

GATS obligati<strong>on</strong>s that showed highly<br />

restrictive commitments.<br />

Due to data implicati<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>the</strong> analysis<br />

was c<strong>on</strong>ducted jointly <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> maritime<br />

and telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s sectors. The<br />

liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of maritime and telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

sectors following <strong>the</strong> EU norms<br />

was found to result in welfare increase of


11.2% and 0.89% respectively in terms<br />

of c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> or successively 5.47%<br />

and 0.74% of GDP. In fact welfare effect<br />

is likely to be lower than shown here, as<br />

<strong>the</strong> calculati<strong>on</strong>s are assuming that liberalizati<strong>on</strong><br />

applies to <strong>the</strong> whole sector that<br />

includes telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s, maritime<br />

as well as o<strong>the</strong>r modes of transport.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> case of Tunisia, <strong>the</strong> maritime transportati<strong>on</strong><br />

restrictiveness index obtained<br />

is equal to 40 percent, and it is equivalent<br />

to a 50% tariff. Given <strong>the</strong> measures<br />

already taken to liberalize <strong>the</strong> sector, this<br />

rate is not so high compared to o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

countries in and outside <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>, but<br />

it remains ra<strong>the</strong>r restrictive compared to<br />

<strong>the</strong> rates obtained for more developed<br />

countries, including <strong>the</strong> EU countries. If<br />

liberalizati<strong>on</strong> refers to <strong>the</strong> adopti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

EU regulati<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> restrictiveness<br />

index would have to be reduced to about<br />

30%, which is approximately <strong>the</strong> rate<br />

obtained in <strong>the</strong> EU countries, and <strong>the</strong><br />

tariff equivalent rate by about as much.<br />

Maritime transport prices would <strong>the</strong>refore<br />

be significantly lowered. In terms of <strong>the</strong><br />

indirect impact <strong>on</strong> commodity prices, and<br />

<strong>on</strong> welfare measured by <strong>the</strong> equivalent<br />

variati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> result may seem weak,<br />

but <strong>the</strong> numbers do not really capture all<br />

<strong>the</strong> gain.<br />

In Morocco, by c<strong>on</strong>verting <strong>the</strong> overall<br />

restrictiveness index for maritime transport<br />

services in Morocco, estimated at<br />

(0.5425), we obtain a tariff-equivalent<br />

of (72 percent). In o<strong>the</strong>r words, existing<br />

restricti<strong>on</strong>s generate an extra cost of<br />

maritime transport services of 72 percent<br />

compared to what would prevail<br />

under full liberalizati<strong>on</strong>. This substantial<br />

cost affects <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy as a whole and<br />

undermines seriously <strong>the</strong> capacity of <strong>the</strong><br />

Moroccan operators to compete effecti-<br />

-57-<br />

vely <strong>on</strong> foreign markets. It also represents<br />

a serious handicap for attracting<br />

foreign investors willing to use Morocco<br />

as an export platform.<br />

In order to assess <strong>the</strong> hypo<strong>the</strong>tical effect,<br />

a 72 percent decrease in <strong>the</strong> price of<br />

maritime services derived from our previous<br />

calculati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy, <strong>the</strong><br />

1998 Input-Output table of <strong>the</strong> Moroccan<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omy has been used. It assumes<br />

in particular that <strong>the</strong> maritime sector<br />

plays roughly <strong>the</strong> same role in <strong>2005</strong> as<br />

in 1998. This assumpti<strong>on</strong> is to some<br />

extent defendable with regard to <strong>the</strong><br />

role of maritime transport statistics, and<br />

<strong>the</strong> current state of reforms covering<br />

various comp<strong>on</strong>ents of <strong>the</strong> logistic chain.<br />

However, <strong>the</strong> serious limitati<strong>on</strong> of welfare<br />

assessment of liberalizing maritime<br />

transport services in Morocco emerges<br />

from <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> 1998 Input-Output<br />

table does not separate transport from<br />

telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

On <strong>the</strong> basis of <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>ducted computati<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

it seems that by aligning Moroccan<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong>s in Maritime transport services<br />

with <strong>the</strong>ir European counterparts<br />

and ensuring that various services are<br />

provided in a competitive envir<strong>on</strong>ment,<br />

would lead to an improvement of c<strong>on</strong>sumers’<br />

welfare captured through total<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> by 3.254 percent. Since in<br />

1998 c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> represented 86.12<br />

percent of GDP, this welfare gain would<br />

translate into an increase of 2.84 percent<br />

in GDP. This is a substantial amount and<br />

reveals <strong>the</strong> magnitude of <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

cost for Morocco due to lack of efficiency<br />

in <strong>the</strong> maritime transport services. This<br />

amount also indicates <strong>the</strong> potential gain<br />

that could be generated <strong>on</strong>ce maritime<br />

sector reforms are fully and effectively<br />

implemented.


In <strong>the</strong> Turkish case, foreign indexes for<br />

Turkey and <strong>the</strong> 15 EU member countries<br />

(<strong>on</strong> average) are calculated as 0.4944<br />

and 0.3270, respectively. In c<strong>on</strong>verting<br />

restrictiveness index obtained above into<br />

its tariff (ad valorem) equivalent, three<br />

alternative scenarios were c<strong>on</strong>sidered.<br />

Scenario A is based <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> assumpti<strong>on</strong><br />

that Turkey will lower her foreign index<br />

(0.4944) to <strong>the</strong> level of <strong>the</strong> EU (0.3270),<br />

if it adopts <strong>the</strong> EU rules and regulati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

in <strong>the</strong> maritime sector as <strong>the</strong>y prevailed<br />

as of <strong>the</strong> end of 1998. In scenario B, <strong>the</strong><br />

degree of existing maritime restricti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

in Turkey is lowered to <strong>the</strong> level of <strong>the</strong><br />

UK (0.2394), where <strong>the</strong> foreign index is<br />

<strong>the</strong> lowest am<strong>on</strong>g all EU member countries<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sidered. Finally, in scenario C, it<br />

is assumed that <strong>the</strong> degree of existing<br />

restricti<strong>on</strong>s in Turkey is reduced by 100<br />

percent (i.e., all restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> trade in<br />

maritime services are removed).<br />

The calculati<strong>on</strong>s reveal that, if Turkey<br />

liberalizes its maritime sector to <strong>the</strong><br />

1998 level for <strong>the</strong> 15 EU member countries,<br />

<strong>the</strong>n Turkish maritime prices will<br />

be reduced by 30.44 percent. A fur<strong>the</strong>r<br />

maritime liberalizati<strong>on</strong> in Turkey to bring<br />

<strong>the</strong> sector to <strong>the</strong> UK’s level will cause<br />

an additi<strong>on</strong>al fall in shipping prices in<br />

<strong>the</strong> amount of 15.92 percent points.<br />

However, a complete eliminati<strong>on</strong> of trade<br />

barriers in Turkish maritime sector is<br />

expected to create a cost fall of 89.9<br />

percent.<br />

To analyze <strong>the</strong> possible welfare effect<br />

of <strong>the</strong> change in <strong>the</strong> price of maritime<br />

transport <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> prices of o<strong>the</strong>r goods<br />

and services, <strong>the</strong> 1996 Input-Output<br />

Table of <strong>the</strong> Turkish ec<strong>on</strong>omy which<br />

has 97 sectors was c<strong>on</strong>sidered. Under<br />

<strong>the</strong> abovementi<strong>on</strong>ed three alternative<br />

scenarios about <strong>the</strong> degree of maritime<br />

-58-<br />

liberalizati<strong>on</strong> in Turkey, <strong>the</strong> welfare of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Turkish society will increase by 0.22,<br />

0.34 or even 0.66 percent respectively.<br />

However, <strong>the</strong>se potential welfare effects<br />

need to be c<strong>on</strong>verted into <strong>the</strong>ir real GDP<br />

growth equivalents. Since during 1996<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> formed 72.95 percent of<br />

GDP, <strong>the</strong> percentage change in welfare<br />

of <strong>the</strong> society is equivalent to 0.1616,<br />

0.2464 or 0.4793 percent increase in<br />

real GDP of Turkey.<br />

It can be c<strong>on</strong>cluded that liberalizati<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong> maritime sector holds a scope for<br />

higher welfare of <strong>the</strong> respective countries,<br />

albeit with varying degrees. The<br />

four countries were found to benefit<br />

from adopting and implementing <strong>the</strong><br />

legislative, regulatory and instituti<strong>on</strong>al<br />

framework of <strong>the</strong> EU maritime transport<br />

sector. This is expected to accrue mainly<br />

due to <strong>the</strong> increase in competiti<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong><br />

maritime transport sector. It is worth<br />

noting that, <strong>on</strong>e of <strong>the</strong> limitati<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>the</strong><br />

Input-Output methodology is that it <strong>on</strong>ly<br />

accounts for static effects. It does not<br />

capture any likely increase in c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

demands for various commodities following<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir price reducti<strong>on</strong>, which would<br />

require informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> price elasticities<br />

of demand for all commodities covered<br />

in <strong>the</strong> input-output table.<br />

Moreover, it can be highlighted that<br />

even if <strong>the</strong>se global static effects appear<br />

“modest”, <strong>the</strong>y remain <strong>the</strong> most significant<br />

for 3 out of <strong>the</strong> 4 countries.<br />

Especially in terms of prices, <strong>the</strong> effect<br />

<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> firms will be far from negligible at<br />

<strong>the</strong> micro ec<strong>on</strong>omic level. As underlined<br />

in <strong>the</strong> first part, <strong>the</strong> firms acquire optimizati<strong>on</strong><br />

behavior to face <strong>the</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

and from this point of view, transportati<strong>on</strong><br />

problems c<strong>on</strong>stitute an obstacle that<br />

is often menti<strong>on</strong>ed. It is obvious that all


means allowing <strong>the</strong> stimulati<strong>on</strong> of firms’<br />

price competitiveness, without having an<br />

effect <strong>on</strong> labor or wage levels (which is<br />

incompatible with <strong>the</strong> social c<strong>on</strong>straints<br />

of <strong>the</strong> MCs) assumes a strategic importance.<br />

Finally, <strong>the</strong> examinati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

problems facing <strong>the</strong> textile and clothing<br />

sectors has also shown that <strong>the</strong> MCs<br />

might, to improve <strong>the</strong>ir value chain,<br />

increase <strong>the</strong> reactivity of <strong>the</strong>ir firms.<br />

Here in additi<strong>on</strong> to <strong>the</strong> prices effect, <strong>the</strong><br />

transport liberalizati<strong>on</strong> becomes also a<br />

major comp<strong>on</strong>ent of a global industrial<br />

project.<br />

Moreover, transport remains a determinant<br />

factor and a major piece in <strong>the</strong><br />

big puzzle of development because <strong>the</strong><br />

existence of a reliable transport sector<br />

is a prec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> for investors and especially<br />

for exporters. It is well established<br />

at least that with an inefficient maritime<br />

transportati<strong>on</strong> system, progress in terms<br />

of investment and growth would be very<br />

hard to achieve.<br />

III. Regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong>: time for<br />

choices<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> of transport naturally<br />

brings to mind <strong>on</strong>e of <strong>the</strong> main missed<br />

opportunities of <strong>the</strong> ten first years of <strong>the</strong><br />

Barcel<strong>on</strong>a process as menti<strong>on</strong>ed in <strong>the</strong><br />

introducti<strong>on</strong>, namely South-South regi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

integrati<strong>on</strong>. The open door strategy<br />

was clearly selected by <strong>the</strong> quasi-totality<br />

of Mediterranean partners, but <strong>the</strong> North-<br />

South axis was still much preferred to a<br />

more regi<strong>on</strong>al dimensi<strong>on</strong>. It is <strong>the</strong> objective<br />

of this chapter to raise <strong>the</strong> questi<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong> coherence of this state of affairs,<br />

and seek <strong>the</strong> reas<strong>on</strong>s that could explain<br />

it or allow proceeding <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> transversal<br />

axis and which might seem essential in<br />

<strong>the</strong> Euro-Mediterranean c<strong>on</strong>text, about<br />

-59-<br />

what <strong>the</strong> European model can c<strong>on</strong>tribute<br />

to <strong>the</strong> latest regi<strong>on</strong>al initiatives.<br />

1. Current internati<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

of MPs<br />

Very few countries are not involved in<br />

some trade agreement or ano<strong>the</strong>r (7<br />

according to Bouet and Mayer, 2003)<br />

and from this point of view MPs are not<br />

atypical at first glance. They are members<br />

of WTO (Egypt, Morocco, Tunisia,<br />

Turkey since 1995, Jordan since 2000);<br />

<strong>the</strong>y signed trade agreements with <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

European neighbours. Moreover, <strong>the</strong><br />

policy of new neighbourliness launched<br />

negotiati<strong>on</strong>s for <strong>the</strong> establishment of<br />

a vast Euro-Mediterranean free trade<br />

area: finally <strong>the</strong>y are parties to diverse<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>al agreements.<br />

The main questi<strong>on</strong> is to know what is <strong>the</strong><br />

degree of coherence in MPs’ trade strategy<br />

and <strong>the</strong> compatibility between <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

multilateral and regi<strong>on</strong>al approaches to<br />

<strong>the</strong> liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of exchanges. To reply<br />

to this questi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>on</strong>e approach c<strong>on</strong>sists of<br />

measuring <strong>the</strong> degree of trade openness<br />

of a country, starting with an assessment<br />

of <strong>the</strong> level and distributi<strong>on</strong> of tariffs and<br />

<strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sequences of n<strong>on</strong>-tariff barriers.<br />

In fact, protecti<strong>on</strong>ism can be defined as<br />

any act that impedes <strong>the</strong> exchange of<br />

goods and services by rendering goods<br />

imported by a nati<strong>on</strong>al actor more costly<br />

than <strong>the</strong> same products <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

market. If <strong>the</strong> price, all taxes included,<br />

of <strong>the</strong>se two identical goods produced in<br />

two different places is <strong>the</strong> same in <strong>the</strong><br />

market under c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>re<br />

is no protecti<strong>on</strong>ism. According to <strong>the</strong>se<br />

indicators <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> extent of opening up of<br />

a domestic market of a country as well<br />

as its export markets, it is possible to<br />

have a better idea of <strong>the</strong> optimal trade


policy of <strong>the</strong>se countries and coherence<br />

between past agreements and optimal<br />

opening strategy (multilateral, regi<strong>on</strong>al,<br />

etc.)<br />

A study undertaken by <strong>the</strong> <strong>Femise</strong><br />

team[35] has used a new database that<br />

offers an assessment of <strong>the</strong> degree of<br />

openness of a country. This was d<strong>on</strong>e<br />

based <strong>on</strong> calculati<strong>on</strong>s carried out <strong>on</strong><br />

a bilateral, detailed and disaggregated<br />

basis which includes <strong>the</strong> degree<br />

of tariffs dispersi<strong>on</strong>s according to <strong>the</strong><br />

goods, which is d<strong>on</strong>e traditi<strong>on</strong>ally, but<br />

also according to <strong>the</strong> partners in agreement<br />

with <strong>the</strong> type of agreement in force<br />

(regi<strong>on</strong>al agreement, preferential treatment)<br />

which is translated into particular<br />

-60-<br />

measures (tariff quotas, specific rights,<br />

etc.). This process offers a more realistic<br />

view of barriers in existing trade, even<br />

if each type of barrier has a different<br />

impact <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> level of exchange which in<br />

turn depends <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> supply and demand<br />

flexibility. It provides an ad valorem<br />

evaluati<strong>on</strong> of some of <strong>the</strong>ir elements it<br />

remains a delicate process.<br />

MPs’ access to markets<br />

Table X15: level of global and sector protecti<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> MPs<br />

The new measure of trade barriers used<br />

here indicates that MPs markets are over<br />

protected. The richer countries apply<br />

a generally lower level of protecti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

However, a sector by sector examinati<strong>on</strong><br />

reveals a totally different reality, namely<br />

Global Agriculture Industry<br />

SM Countries Algeria 13,8% 17,9% 13,5%<br />

Egypt 29,0% 13,8% 30,3%<br />

Jordan 11,2% 11,8% 11,1%<br />

Leban<strong>on</strong> 3,9% 8,8% 3,4%<br />

Libya 21,0% 11,9% 21,8%<br />

Morocco 20,9% 43,9% 19,0%<br />

Syria 16,4% 12,1% 16,8%<br />

Tunisia 20,2% 57,5% 17,1%<br />

Turkey 6,1% 42,0% 3,1%<br />

OECD Countries Australia 5,2% 1,2% 5,5%<br />

Canada 3,5% 15,2% 2,6%<br />

EU 3,5% 17,2% 2,6%<br />

Japan 4,1% 37,4% 1,5%<br />

Switzerland 3,9% 43,7% 1,0%<br />

USA 2,4% 5,1% 2,2%<br />

Emerging Countries Argentina 12,5% 11,5% 12,6%<br />

Brazil 11,8% 10,2% 11,9%<br />

China 14,1% 23,6% 13,3%<br />

India 33,4% 59,2% 30,1%<br />

Pakistan 19,1% 26,9% 18,1%<br />

South Africa 8,5% 19,4% 7,4%<br />

LDC Bangladesh 17,4% 20,0% 17,1%<br />

Cambodgia 12,9% 12,7% 13,0%<br />

Chad 15,8% 21,5% 14,7%<br />

Ethiopia 14,4% 17,0% 13,9%<br />

Lesotho 8,1% 20,7% 6,4%<br />

Madagascar 4,4% 4,8% 4,3%<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong> Study FEM22-36, based <strong>on</strong> database MacMap-HS6 and author’s calculati<strong>on</strong>


that in terms of <strong>the</strong> agricultural markets<br />

it was found that <strong>the</strong> OECD countries’<br />

protecti<strong>on</strong> is as str<strong>on</strong>g as that calculated<br />

for MPs (table x15). Within <strong>the</strong><br />

group of developing countries, <strong>the</strong> level<br />

of protecti<strong>on</strong> is in general higher and<br />

more homogeneous than in <strong>the</strong> richer<br />

countries. There are several excepti<strong>on</strong>s:<br />

Madagascar has a free exchange policy<br />

and Lesotho has tariff barriers which<br />

vary from <strong>on</strong>e sector to ano<strong>the</strong>r.<br />

A comparis<strong>on</strong> of MPs performance <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

global level with that of countries with<br />

intermediate revenues[36] underlines<br />

<strong>the</strong> high degree of protecti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

-61-<br />

domestic markets, specially in Libya,<br />

Morocco, Tunisia and Egypt (figure 9).<br />

Turkey is relatively more open than<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r MPs except for Leban<strong>on</strong>. This<br />

reflects <strong>the</strong> influence of EU, through <strong>the</strong><br />

customs uni<strong>on</strong> agreement and prospects<br />

of joining <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic Uni<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong>reby obliging <strong>the</strong> country to align<br />

itself with EU practices. Never<strong>the</strong>less,<br />

Turkey’s agricultural sector remains over<br />

protected. This differentiated treatment<br />

of <strong>the</strong> industrial and agricultural sector<br />

is comm<strong>on</strong> in all countries. Only Egypt,<br />

Syria and Libya give less protecti<strong>on</strong> to<br />

agriculture than to industry where certain<br />

activities are nascent.<br />

Figure 9: comparis<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> protecti<strong>on</strong> level in <strong>the</strong> world, imports<br />

Figure 10: comparis<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> protecti<strong>on</strong> level in <strong>the</strong> world, exports<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong> Study FEM22-36


A more refined analysis of protecti<strong>on</strong><br />

per type of goods c<strong>on</strong>firms that it is high<br />

for certain agricultural products, such as<br />

cereals in Japan, meat in Switzerland,<br />

etc. as well as products of key sectors<br />

in <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy (clothing in Egypt, vehicles<br />

in Syria). This reflects <strong>the</strong> weight of<br />

lobbies or adopti<strong>on</strong> of policies to develop<br />

new activities which should be shielded<br />

from global competiti<strong>on</strong> until <strong>the</strong>y are<br />

ready to c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>t it.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> data used allows <strong>the</strong><br />

tracing of <strong>the</strong> level of bilateral protecti<strong>on</strong><br />

that is <strong>the</strong> degree of access of a country<br />

to <strong>the</strong> market of its partner (table x15).<br />

Any interpretati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong>se figures must<br />

be made cautiously[37] because <strong>the</strong>y<br />

refer to <strong>the</strong> type of agreement that<br />

a country has with ano<strong>the</strong>r (Morocco<br />

has c<strong>on</strong>cluded accords with Libya and<br />

Algeria and trade is free between <strong>the</strong>se<br />

countries). But also <strong>the</strong>y indicate <strong>the</strong><br />

compositi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> flow of exchange<br />

and respective specializati<strong>on</strong>s which, <strong>the</strong><br />

more <strong>the</strong>y are similar to those in partner<br />

countries, <strong>the</strong> more <strong>the</strong>y are driven to lift<br />

barriers (for example, garment exports<br />

Table X16: level of bilateral protecti<strong>on</strong>, imports, 2001[38]<br />

-62-<br />

from Turkey are str<strong>on</strong>gly penalized in<br />

exchanges with Egypt as opposed to,<br />

for example, petroleum and gas exports<br />

of Algeria or Libya which benefit from a<br />

quasi free access to all markets). The<br />

less<strong>on</strong>s learnt from this approach are:<br />

√ In general, MPs str<strong>on</strong>gly discriminate<br />

against <strong>the</strong>ir partners in imports. This<br />

is certainly due to existence of trade<br />

agreements but mostly to heterogeneity<br />

of tariffs which <strong>the</strong>y impose;<br />

√ Most countries, members of WTO,<br />

reserve <strong>the</strong> right to impose tariffs<br />

that significantly exceeded those set<br />

by agreements (16.2% higher for<br />

Tunisia, 24.8% for Turkey) with <strong>the</strong><br />

excepti<strong>on</strong> of Egypt.<br />

√ MPs exports to EU could develop due<br />

to weak imposed tariffs as compared<br />

to those practiced in o<strong>the</strong>r countries<br />

such as <strong>the</strong> United States and <strong>the</strong> rest<br />

of OECD. This explains <strong>the</strong>ir specializati<strong>on</strong><br />

in textile-clothing for example<br />

as <strong>the</strong> EU market is nearby and also<br />

<strong>on</strong>e of <strong>the</strong> richest in <strong>the</strong> world.<br />

Partners<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>Report</str<strong>on</strong>g>er Algeria Egypt EU Jordan Leban<strong>on</strong> Libya Morocco Rest OECD Syria Tunisia Turkey USA<br />

Algeria 14,6% 14,6% 15,3% 18,4% 8,6% 0,0% 13,7% 12,8% 19,1% 19,7% 12,0%<br />

Egypt 7,3% 28,6% 10,2% 17,6% 3,2% 14,0% 24,1% 23,8% 15,1% 77,2% 28,2%<br />

Jordan 18,8% 5,8% 12,6% 7,9% 3,6% 4,5% 10,3% 5,0% 7,1% 16,2% 9,9%<br />

Leban<strong>on</strong> 2,0% 3,3% 4,7% 5,8% 2,3% 1,8% 3,0% 2,2% 4,5% 7,8% 3,8%<br />

Libya 37,9% 7,6% 21,6% 5,2% 11,6% 0,0% 18,5% 24,0% 7,0% 18,7% 20,5%<br />

Morocco 0,0% 20,5% 18,9% 11,1% 16,6% 0,0% 20,9% 12,7% 15,8% 34,1% 19,5%<br />

Syria 10,1% 16,1% 20,0% 10,8% 17,2% 7,1% 9,7% 16,2% 18,3% 27,7% 14,0%<br />

Tunisia 4,0% 15,9% 12,7% 15,7% 21,8% 4,7% 16,6% 23,2% 12,8% 40,1% 23,7%<br />

Turkey 0,6% 12,0% 3,3% 5,4% 11,4% 1,3% 12,1% 6,2% 6,6% 16,1% 6,2%<br />

Australia 2,7% 7,7% 5,8% 12,7% 4,4% 5,0% 10,4% 5,2% 5,7% 13,8% 12,0% 3,3%<br />

Canada 0,0% 4,5% 4,7% 9,9% 4,7% 0,4% 8,0% 2,6% 1,1% 9,8% 8,0% 0,5%<br />

EU 0,1% 1,7% 3,0% 2,6% 2,8% 0,3% 1,4% 3,9% 0,5% 2,1% 1,5% 3,8%<br />

Japan 0,9% 7,2% 4,6% 6,3% 6,9% 0,2% 6,5% 3,0% 1,4% 6,4% 5,0% 3,0%<br />

Switzerland 0,0% 6,7% 4,1% 18,2% 7,9% 0,0% 8,1% 3,9% 1,8% 3,5% 6,9% 5,4%<br />

USA 0,2% 3,7% 2,7% 4,2% 2,3% 0,2% 5,8% 1,4% 1,1% 6,3% 5,9%<br />

Argentina 0,2% 13,0% 13,8% 10,7% 15,3% 1,0% 7,9% 12,9% 7,7% 9,5% 16,2% 13,2%<br />

Brazil 0,4% 10,9% 13,9% 7,1% 10,3% 1,0% 7,9% 13,2% 5,0% 11,6% 15,7% 10,6%<br />

China 4,6% 10,6% 16,4% 10,3% 13,8% 1,7% 9,8% 14,3% 6,8% 16,2% 19,2% 13,7%<br />

India 15,6% 24,6% 32,9% 29,4% 32,1% 31,2% 30,4% 33,4% 13,4% 31,0% 34,1% 30,8%<br />

Pakistan 9,6% 12,4% 19,4% 15,1% 17,6% 12,6% 12,6% 20,1% 7,8% 17,5% 21,1% 17,7%<br />

South Africa 1,8% 10,3% 8,2% 4,7% 14,7% 5,3% 5,3% 7,9% 8,5% 6,0% 15,6% 8,0%<br />

Bangladesch 13,3% 21,3% 14,8% 13,0% 19,6% 17,3% 15,5% 15,8% 7,4% 14,4% 23,2% 15,8%<br />

Cambodgia 3,8% 9,1% 14,4% 9,6% 15,6% 6,4% 9,1% 12,9% 10,9% 9,5% 14,2% 15,7%<br />

Chad 11,3% 15,9% 14,8% 11,5% 15,8% 7,5% 23,3% 13,3% 20,4% 24,0% 18,5% 11,9%<br />

Ethiopia 5,9% 9,4% 14,8% 9,0% 15,1% 0,8% 26,4% 9,7% 27,3% 21,0% 16,8% 9,4%<br />

Lesotho 3,6% 6,9% 7,3% 6,1% 9,2% 2,5% 3,1% 7,8% 15,5% 7,7% 13,2% 9,6%<br />

Madagascar 0,7% 0,0% 4,5% 2,3% 4,9% 0,3% 5,8% 4,7% 5,8% 4,9% 3,7% 3,2%<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong> Study FEM22-36, based <strong>on</strong> database MacMap-HS6 and author’s calculati<strong>on</strong>


√ Tariffs imposed by MPs <strong>on</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r MPs<br />

are am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> highest, a matter that<br />

is not c<strong>on</strong>ducive to South-South integrati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

√ High tariffs are imposed <strong>on</strong> imports of<br />

minor importance for <strong>the</strong> well-being<br />

of c<strong>on</strong>sumers in <strong>the</strong> case of Turkey,<br />

Tunisia and Morocco but not for <strong>the</strong><br />

rest of MPs.<br />

Specializati<strong>on</strong> of MPs, as previously<br />

menti<strong>on</strong>ed, equally influences <strong>the</strong> forms<br />

of integrati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> flows that are c<strong>on</strong>venient<br />

to MPs as well as <strong>the</strong> burden of<br />

tariff protecti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir flows. It has<br />

been noted that:<br />

√ The degree of diversificati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

exports depends <strong>on</strong> a number of<br />

factors such as <strong>the</strong> industrializati<strong>on</strong><br />

process, established open door policy<br />

and geographic c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

flows of exchanges. The proximity of<br />

Maghreb countries to <strong>the</strong> EU explains<br />

<strong>the</strong> relatively c<strong>on</strong>centrated structure<br />

of exports from <strong>the</strong> Maghreb. There<br />

are two c<strong>on</strong>sequences: first, Maghreb<br />

Table X17: level of bilateral protecti<strong>on</strong>, exports, 2001<br />

-63-<br />

countries will be more vulnerable to<br />

fluctuati<strong>on</strong>s in <strong>the</strong> European ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

cycle; sec<strong>on</strong>d, c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

exports, in <strong>the</strong> absolute, weakens <strong>the</strong><br />

resilience of <strong>the</strong>ir ec<strong>on</strong>omies.<br />

√ Inclusi<strong>on</strong> of MPs in internati<strong>on</strong>al markets<br />

essentially occurs <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> basis<br />

of comparative advantages resting<br />

<strong>on</strong> differences of relative productivity<br />

or factorial endowments. Geographic<br />

proximity to EU explains <strong>the</strong> intensive<br />

exchanges and <strong>the</strong> characteristics of<br />

supply largely determine <strong>the</strong> compositi<strong>on</strong><br />

of exchanges. Exchanges are<br />

principally inter-branch[39]. However,<br />

a development of an intra- branch<br />

trade can be observed.<br />

√ MPs are outstanding in <strong>the</strong> export<br />

of manufactured products with<br />

<strong>the</strong> excepti<strong>on</strong> of Algeria, which<br />

has regressed while Egypt stagnates.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>cerning Turkey and Israel,<br />

<strong>the</strong> decline in agro-foods produce<br />

has been more than compensated<br />

by <strong>the</strong> good results of c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

goods and equipment, respectively.<br />

Importer<br />

Exporter Algeria Egypt EU Jordan Leban<strong>on</strong> Libya Morocco Rest OECD Syria Tunisia Turkey USA<br />

Algeria 7,3% 0,1% 18,8% 2,0% 37,9% 0,00% 1,5% 10,1% 4,0% 0,6% 0,2%<br />

Egypt 14,6% 1,7% 5,8% 3,3% 7,6% 20,5% 7,4% 16,1% 15,9% 12,0% 3,7%<br />

Jordan 15,3% 10,2% 2,6% 5,8% 5,2% 11,1% 10,2% 10,8% 15,7% 5,4% 4,2%<br />

Leban<strong>on</strong> 18,4% 17,6% 2,8% 7,9% 11,6% 16,6% 12,3% 17,2% 21,8% 11,4% 2,3%<br />

Morocco 0,0% 14,0% 1,4% 4,5% 1,8% 0,0% 8,2% 9,7% 16,6% 12,1% 5,8%<br />

Syria 12,8% 23,8% 0,5% 5,0% 2,2% 24,0% 12,7% 5,3% 12,8% 6,6% 1,1%<br />

Tunisia 19,1% 15,1% 2,1% 7,1% 4,5% 7,0% 15,8% 7,0% 18,3% 16,1% 6,3%<br />

Turkey 19,7% 77,2% 1,5% 16,2% 7,8% 18,7% 34,1% 8,3% 27,7% 40,1% 5,9%<br />

Australia 11,1% 11,7% 9,0% 6,9% 2,5% 15,5% 31,4% 10,3% 8,3% 30,4% 17,6% 2,0%<br />

Canada 10,3% 10,1% 5,1% 7,8% 3,0% 16,0% 22,1% 5,2% 10,1% 38,7% 10,6% 0,1%<br />

EU 8,8% 5,7% 2% 5,9% 5,1% 92,7% 18,5% 3,3% 8,5% 8,4% 1,0% 1,5%<br />

Japan 12,9% 17,7% 4,3% 10,9% 3,0% 21,7% 17,9% 5,6% 17,6% 20;6% 4,4% 1,9%<br />

Switzerland 12,4% 12,8% 0,8% 8,2% 2,8% 15,2% 16,8% 3,4% 7,9% 22,2% 0,6% 2,2%<br />

USA 12,0% 28,2% 3,8% 9,9% 3,8% 20,5% 19,5% 3,1% 14,0% 23,7% 6,2% -<br />

Argentina 14,0% 16,0% 6,8% 9,8% 5,0% 24,4% 28,0% 15,5% 16,7% 33,2% 16,7% 3,5%<br />

Brazil 14,6% 22,8% 6,7% 11,1% 4,8% 19,4% 26,6% 14,6% 18,0% 25,0% 18,6% 3,0%<br />

China 19,9% 142,6% 4,3% 15,9% 5,5% 18,9% 28,4% 5,6% 25,1% 32,0% 9,4% 4,5%<br />

India 17,0% 51,6% 5,6% 10,4% 3,4% 9,8% 33,8% 11,1% 13,4% 30,3% 14,5% 4,6%<br />

Pakistan 17,8% 45,0% 2,7% 3,9% 2,8% 14,1% 38,6% 14,7% 30,3% 25,9% 9,1% 8,2%<br />

South Africa 14,8% 35,2% 3,3% 14,1% 5,7% 17,1% 28,0% 5,9% 17,0% 28,8% 11,1% 0,7%<br />

Bangladesch 18,1% 63,9% 0,7% 5,7% 3,3% 8,0% 30,5% 6,7% 17,9% 28,3% 7,8% 11,7%<br />

Cambodgia 15,5% 42,4% 1,6% 4,4% 1,9% 10,2% 36,6% 7,5% 23,8% 28,4% 8,6% 12,4%<br />

Chad 5,5% 6,1% 0,0% 1,1% 0,5% 1,4% 4,0% 0,6% 28,8% 1,8% 0,2% 2,0%<br />

Ethiopia 14,6% 28,6% 3,0% 12,6% 4,7% 21,6% 18,9% 6,0% 20,0% 12,7% 3,3% 2,7%<br />

Lesotho 8,4% 13,0% 0,7% 2,6% 1,7% 27,1% 10,9% 7,0% 8,3% 10,4% 2,2% 12,0%<br />

Madagascar 23,4% 0,0% 1,5% 23,4% 4,0% 6,5% 33,1% 7,2% 22,8% 34,8% 19,3% 5,0%<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong> Study FEM22-36, based <strong>on</strong> database MacMap-HS6 and author’s calculati<strong>on</strong>


N<strong>on</strong>e<strong>the</strong>less, since <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>on</strong>d part of<br />

<strong>the</strong> 1990s, market shares gained by<br />

Morocco and Tunisia suddenly stopped,<br />

largely because enterprises in<br />

<strong>the</strong> textile sector were paralyzed by<br />

<strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sequences of <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong><br />

multi-fiber agreement and decelerati<strong>on</strong><br />

of investments.<br />

√ Except for Algeria, all MPs had a<br />

trade deficit, <strong>the</strong> origin being in<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir exchanges with EU (except for<br />

Egypt), more specifically in manufactured<br />

goods. The offsetting of<br />

this deficit <strong>the</strong> 1980s was driven by<br />

<strong>the</strong> increase in exports and decrease<br />

in imports owing to <strong>the</strong> slow down in<br />

European demand and <strong>the</strong> gains in<br />

market share. Turkey, which enjoys<br />

a certain status in <strong>the</strong> customs<br />

uni<strong>on</strong> with EU since January 1996,<br />

saw its imports coming from EU 15<br />

grow rapidly whereas its exports<br />

remained very diversified. Hence,<br />

<strong>the</strong> country was able to profit from<br />

<strong>the</strong> opportunity to import new technologies<br />

and cheaper products to<br />

reactivate its exchanges and reduce<br />

its deficit (devaluati<strong>on</strong> of its currency<br />

also helped).<br />

√ Based <strong>on</strong> a gravity model at <strong>the</strong><br />

sectoral level, an estimati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

effects <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> imports and exports of<br />

each country relative to <strong>the</strong> welfare<br />

of <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sidered country have been<br />

studied. Also <strong>the</strong> capitalist intensity<br />

of <strong>the</strong>ir trade and its structure,<br />

<strong>the</strong> presence of a comm<strong>on</strong><br />

language or grounds, or comm<strong>on</strong><br />

history were also c<strong>on</strong>sidered. It has<br />

been shown that <strong>the</strong> level of tariff<br />

protecti<strong>on</strong> affects more significantly<br />

MPs imports than <strong>the</strong>ir exports and<br />

<strong>the</strong> flexibility of exchange flows to<br />

-64-<br />

tariffs is high[40]. This refers to <strong>the</strong><br />

existence of preferential access of<br />

MPs to certain large markets such as<br />

those of <strong>the</strong> EU. Certainly, but this<br />

also means that a tariffs dismantling<br />

will cause a significant increase in<br />

exchanges, greater than that obtained<br />

generally in this type of analysis<br />

which does not take tariffs into<br />

account or <strong>the</strong> fact that MPs can not<br />

influence <strong>the</strong> market price imposed<br />

by <strong>the</strong>ir trade partners. Bey<strong>on</strong>d this,<br />

c<strong>on</strong>straints imposed by <strong>the</strong> majority<br />

of MPs <strong>on</strong> imports, especially more<br />

advanced technologies have had a<br />

negative impact <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir adjustment<br />

capacity thus hampering <strong>the</strong> upgrading<br />

of <strong>the</strong>ir industry.<br />

√ It appears as well that sharing a<br />

comm<strong>on</strong> language encourages MP<br />

exports and imports, located as <strong>the</strong>y<br />

are in <strong>the</strong> proximity of countries<br />

whose col<strong>on</strong>ies <strong>the</strong>y were in <strong>the</strong><br />

past, whereas having a comm<strong>on</strong> border<br />

has no impact <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> intensity<br />

of trade. This illustrates <strong>the</strong> difficulties<br />

of South-South integrati<strong>on</strong>, even<br />

when <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> importer market<br />

plays a significant role. N<strong>on</strong>e<strong>the</strong>less,<br />

estimati<strong>on</strong>s that were made dem<strong>on</strong>strate<br />

that <strong>the</strong> effect of lifting tariff<br />

barriers of MPs vis-à-vis o<strong>the</strong>r MPs<br />

would <strong>on</strong>ly have a marginal effect<br />

<strong>on</strong> intra-z<strong>on</strong>e exchanges and that<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r elements should complement<br />

South-South trade integrati<strong>on</strong> policy<br />

in order to help achieve a rapprochement<br />

with EU.<br />

√ Not forgetting, as noted above, <strong>the</strong><br />

importance of transportati<strong>on</strong> costs,<br />

by reform of different sectors, particularly<br />

maritime transport as well as<br />

by creati<strong>on</strong> of new infrastructures.


Evaluati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> advantages of dif-<br />

ferent forms of integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

On <strong>the</strong> basis of <strong>the</strong>se reports, <strong>the</strong> study<br />

tries to determine which type of open<br />

policy is <strong>the</strong> best for MPs. Simulati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

made according to <strong>the</strong> MIRAGE model<br />

indicate that:<br />

√ A free-exchange South-South agreement<br />

will benefit Turkey and Tunisia<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly and very marginally Morocco,<br />

which is relatively very protecti<strong>on</strong>ist<br />

towards o<strong>the</strong>r MPs. The first<br />

will increase its exports, namely TC<br />

towards MPs and <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>on</strong>d will<br />

direct its exports towards MP and EU<br />

countries and gain ground thanks<br />

to <strong>the</strong> benefits of competiti<strong>on</strong> which<br />

will come about <strong>on</strong> opening up South<br />

markets.<br />

√ The same type of agreement signed<br />

between <strong>the</strong> EU and each MP separately<br />

will raise living standards in<br />

Turkey, Tunisia, and Morocco but<br />

not <strong>the</strong> rest of <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean<br />

where <strong>the</strong>y would decline. Morocco<br />

and Tunisia will c<strong>on</strong>sequently benefit<br />

from <strong>the</strong> significant exchanges (respectively<br />

+54% and +48%) generated<br />

by liberalizati<strong>on</strong> and <strong>the</strong> trade<br />

in agricultural goods with EU will<br />

compensate <strong>the</strong> fall in exchanges<br />

between MPs. The budgetary equilibrium<br />

will suffer greatly from <strong>the</strong> loss<br />

of earnings due to aboliti<strong>on</strong> of tariffs,<br />

but employment, income and investment<br />

will progress. This opening up<br />

strategy will entail a profound modificati<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>the</strong> productive structure.<br />

Sectors destined to witness a reducti<strong>on</strong><br />

of activities are milk and meat<br />

for Turkey, Morocco, and Tunisia, and<br />

TC and agriculture for o<strong>the</strong>r MPs.<br />

-65-<br />

O<strong>the</strong>rs will greatly profit from this<br />

growth in exchanges such as TC sectors<br />

in Turkey, Morocco (more than<br />

agricultural products) and Tunisia.<br />

However, this strategy does not<br />

appear best suited to MPs as a z<strong>on</strong>e,<br />

<strong>the</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> of traffic benefiting some<br />

will be compensated by <strong>the</strong> rerouting<br />

of traffic away from o<strong>the</strong>rs. For<br />

example, in <strong>the</strong> TC sector, creati<strong>on</strong><br />

of traffic with EU affects intra-branch<br />

exchanges. The comparative advantages<br />

of Morocco, Tunisia and Turkey<br />

are such that activity is <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> rise<br />

and net trade balance vis-à-vis EU in<br />

this sector is improving. As competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

with o<strong>the</strong>r MPs in this domain<br />

is weak, EU will prefer <strong>the</strong> products<br />

of Morocco, Tunisia, and Turkey and<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir net trade balance vis-à-vis EU<br />

will deteriorate as well as <strong>the</strong>ir terms<br />

of exchange. This will undermine <strong>the</strong><br />

global efficiency of this strategy.<br />

√ Finally, multilateral trade liberalizati<strong>on</strong><br />

will profit a priori all MPs but<br />

less so Turkey. Adjustment costs,<br />

more important than those in <strong>the</strong><br />

two examples previously envisaged,<br />

must be taken into account<br />

(increased unemployment in sectors<br />

exposed to foreign competiti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

future of agriculture, massive reallocati<strong>on</strong><br />

of producti<strong>on</strong> factors) and<br />

this cannot be accomplished by this<br />

model. Results are <strong>the</strong>refore to be<br />

handled with care, but this strategy<br />

will generate a str<strong>on</strong>g traffic that<br />

will mainly boost TC producti<strong>on</strong> in<br />

Tunisia and Morocco and cereals in<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r MPs, hence a tangible growth<br />

in GDP and wages.<br />

Some will suggest that a regi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

approach could serve as a springboard


for a multilateral opening. The advan-<br />

tage will be a soft and progressive tran-<br />

siti<strong>on</strong> that will facilitate <strong>the</strong> reallocati<strong>on</strong><br />

of producti<strong>on</strong> factors whose mobility is<br />

not perfect and this implies adjustment<br />

costs. However, such an approach does<br />

not always culminate in a multilateral<br />

agreement. This is <strong>on</strong>ly possible if <strong>the</strong><br />

latter requires <strong>the</strong> same adjustments as<br />

a regi<strong>on</strong>al accord in all o<strong>the</strong>r cases, and<br />

<strong>the</strong> country c<strong>on</strong>cerned will have to bear<br />

<strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sequences of two transiti<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

An analysis of <strong>the</strong> situati<strong>on</strong> of MPs in<br />

terms of structural c<strong>on</strong>gruence indicates<br />

that if for Turkey and o<strong>the</strong>r MPs an<br />

appropriate means to prepare complete<br />

liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of exchanges <strong>on</strong> a multilateral<br />

basis may be to c<strong>on</strong>clude a freeexchange<br />

agreement with <strong>the</strong> EU, for<br />

Morocco <strong>the</strong> situati<strong>on</strong> is not that clear<br />

cut. As for Tunisia, a regi<strong>on</strong>al agreement<br />

with o<strong>the</strong>r MPs will be preferable<br />

(table x18).<br />

It remains that behind <strong>the</strong> purely<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic aspects, <strong>the</strong>re are equally<br />

important political and social effects,<br />

a situati<strong>on</strong> which <strong>the</strong> European c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong><br />

had largely witnessed itself.<br />

It is evident that <strong>the</strong> current situati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

with a North-South orientati<strong>on</strong>, is not<br />

satisfactory and that <strong>the</strong> main factor<br />

of re-equilibrium rests <strong>on</strong> initiatives<br />

like Agadir or GAFTA. Therefore, it is<br />

interesting to raise <strong>the</strong> questi<strong>on</strong> of<br />

steps to be taken to transform <strong>the</strong>se<br />

accords into more profound regi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

integrati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Table X18: indicator of structural c<strong>on</strong>gruence<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong> study FEM22-36<br />

-66-<br />

2. European integrati<strong>on</strong>, a model for<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>al initiatives in <strong>the</strong> South<br />

Regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong> has in <strong>the</strong> past years<br />

become a global objective. Integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

takes several forms, from <strong>the</strong> creati<strong>on</strong><br />

of free-exchange areas, comm<strong>on</strong><br />

markets, up to more profound c<strong>on</strong>figurati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

such as ec<strong>on</strong>omic and political<br />

uni<strong>on</strong>s. Regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong> is supposed<br />

to maximize <strong>the</strong> well being of a nati<strong>on</strong><br />

and reinforce <strong>the</strong> bargaining power of a<br />

regi<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> internati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text.<br />

This secti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> report examines <strong>the</strong><br />

capacity of MPs to establish a str<strong>on</strong>g<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong>. As most MPs are<br />

also Arab countries, it was not possible<br />

to exclude from <strong>the</strong> analysis <strong>the</strong><br />

attempts at Arab uni<strong>on</strong>s, namely because<br />

MPs were am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> most active<br />

in c<strong>on</strong>cluding agreements in <strong>the</strong> Arab<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>. The secti<strong>on</strong> which is based <strong>on</strong> a<br />

<strong>Femise</strong> study (FEM22-07) will principally<br />

refer to Arab integrati<strong>on</strong> and highlight<br />

similarities and differences and suggest<br />

political recommendati<strong>on</strong>s for <strong>the</strong> Arab<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>. Seven different aspects of integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

will be discussed, that is, commercial<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>s, laws of competiti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

c<strong>on</strong>vergence of public policy in finance<br />

and fiscal matters, m<strong>on</strong>etary policy, <strong>the</strong><br />

agricultural questi<strong>on</strong>, social policy and<br />

migratory flows.<br />

Trade Relati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

It is interesting to see that between<br />

1990 and 2004, <strong>the</strong> number of enac-<br />

Turkey Morocco Tunisia O<strong>the</strong>rs MP<br />

South South/Multi. 94,1% 94,5% 96,3% 97,7%<br />

North South/Multi. 98,5% 93,5% 91,5% 98,1%


ted regi<strong>on</strong>al trade agreements (RTAs)<br />

increased from 50 to around 230 globally.<br />

The mean number of RTAs that a<br />

country bel<strong>on</strong>gs to is six.<br />

Over <strong>the</strong> years, several RTAs have been<br />

initiated between Arab countries. History<br />

of <strong>the</strong>se agreements dates back to<br />

1950, when <strong>the</strong> Treaty for Joint Defense<br />

and Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Cooperati<strong>on</strong> was formed.<br />

As <strong>the</strong> title suggests, this was a form<br />

of cooperati<strong>on</strong> ra<strong>the</strong>r than integrati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Around <strong>the</strong> same period, integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

attempts were taking place in Europe<br />

as well. The European story started with<br />

<strong>the</strong> formati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> European Coal and<br />

Steel Community (ECSC) by Germany,<br />

France, Britain, and <strong>the</strong> Benelux countries<br />

(Belgium, <strong>the</strong> Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands, and<br />

Luxembourg). While European integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

was streng<strong>the</strong>ned <strong>on</strong> both <strong>the</strong> vertical<br />

and horiz<strong>on</strong>tal axis, Arab integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

included more countries yet did not<br />

seem to deepen.<br />

Later, o<strong>the</strong>r RTAs were formed, including<br />

<strong>the</strong> Agreement <strong>on</strong> Trade Facilitati<strong>on</strong><br />

and Regulating Transit Trade in 1953,<br />

which was to exempt Arab-originated<br />

products from tariffs as a form of preferential<br />

treatment. 1953 also featured<br />

<strong>the</strong> Agreement for Paying <strong>the</strong> Current<br />

Transacti<strong>on</strong>s and Movement of Capital<br />

in <strong>the</strong> same year, which c<strong>on</strong>stituted <strong>on</strong>ly<br />

a set of unbinding recommendati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

and <strong>the</strong>refore remained idle. These two<br />

agreements were followed by <strong>the</strong> Arab<br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Uni<strong>on</strong> Agreement in 1957,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Arab Comm<strong>on</strong> Market Agreement in<br />

1964, and <strong>the</strong> Agreement <strong>on</strong> Facilitati<strong>on</strong><br />

and Development of Trade in 1983.<br />

However, <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong>se<br />

agreements to regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong> was<br />

very modest. This is primarily due to<br />

-67-<br />

<strong>the</strong> vague wording of <strong>the</strong>se agreements,<br />

which was often intended to guarantee<br />

<strong>the</strong> approval of all parties involved.<br />

This makes <strong>the</strong>se agreements weak and<br />

unbinding. In additi<strong>on</strong>, RTAs are often<br />

characterized as being too ambitious,<br />

given <strong>the</strong> circumstances <strong>the</strong>y have to<br />

functi<strong>on</strong> under, which in turn infest trade<br />

partners with frustrati<strong>on</strong> as a result of<br />

not attaining <strong>the</strong> announced goals and<br />

objectives. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, RTAs generally<br />

lack a clear visi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> achievements<br />

required. Also, <strong>the</strong>se RTAs are frequently<br />

intended as political slogans that are not<br />

put into acti<strong>on</strong>. Integrati<strong>on</strong> is also generally<br />

selective as so<strong>on</strong> as c<strong>on</strong>troversial<br />

issues emerge, especially that partners<br />

want to always be winners and are not<br />

willing to sacrifice part of <strong>the</strong>ir immediate<br />

benefit for future gains.<br />

Several ec<strong>on</strong>omic and instituti<strong>on</strong>al<br />

reas<strong>on</strong>s have hindered <strong>the</strong> process of<br />

integrati<strong>on</strong>. From an ec<strong>on</strong>omic perspective,<br />

<strong>the</strong> likeness of producti<strong>on</strong> and<br />

export compositi<strong>on</strong> of countries of <strong>the</strong><br />

Box : Spotlight <strong>on</strong> GCC<br />

The Gulf Cooperati<strong>on</strong> Council (GCC)<br />

is yet <strong>on</strong>e of <strong>the</strong> successful examples<br />

of sub-regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong>. Formed in<br />

1981, <strong>the</strong> Council was meant to enhance<br />

cooperati<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g six countries that<br />

have c<strong>on</strong>gruent political, social, and ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, namely United Arab<br />

Emirates, Bahrain, Saudi Arabia, Oman,<br />

Qatar, and Kuwait. The council started<br />

out with limited specific objectives, such<br />

as <strong>the</strong> GCC free trade area. Since this<br />

aim has been successfully attained, GCC<br />

countries have recently c<strong>on</strong>sidered going<br />

a step fur<strong>the</strong>r and creating a customs<br />

uni<strong>on</strong> and a GCC comm<strong>on</strong> market. In<br />

2001, GCC countries have approved a<br />

more comprehensive ec<strong>on</strong>omic agreement<br />

which fur<strong>the</strong>r detailed <strong>the</strong> new<br />

structure of GCC ec<strong>on</strong>omic integrati<strong>on</strong>.


egi<strong>on</strong> under study as well as <strong>the</strong> lack<br />

of c<strong>on</strong>gruence between <strong>on</strong>e country’s<br />

exports and ano<strong>the</strong>r country’s imports<br />

prevent <strong>the</strong> deepening of trade relati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> strategy of import substituti<strong>on</strong><br />

prevalent in many countries,<br />

coupled with high tariff protecti<strong>on</strong> and<br />

<strong>the</strong> large size of <strong>the</strong> public sector, are<br />

fur<strong>the</strong>r hindrances. Moreover, <strong>the</strong>re is a<br />

huge disparity between tariff rates and<br />

income am<strong>on</strong>g countries of <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>,<br />

as well as <strong>the</strong>ir ec<strong>on</strong>omic structure (see<br />

Figure 11).<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong> to <strong>the</strong> above-menti<strong>on</strong>ed ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

obstacles, integrati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> Arab<br />

regi<strong>on</strong> faces a number of instituti<strong>on</strong>al<br />

difficulties. One of <strong>the</strong> major drawbacks<br />

is <strong>the</strong> absence of an adequate transportati<strong>on</strong><br />

system. It is interesting to know,<br />

for example, that while <strong>the</strong>re are two<br />

daily flights between Cairo and different<br />

parts of Germany, <strong>the</strong>re are <strong>on</strong>ly<br />

-68-<br />

two weekly flights between Cairo and<br />

Casablanca, Morocco.<br />

The major instituti<strong>on</strong>al handicap, however,<br />

is <strong>the</strong> lack of appropriate supranati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

instituti<strong>on</strong>s that would govern <strong>the</strong><br />

whole process of integrati<strong>on</strong>. Instead,<br />

MPs use an intergovernmental approach,<br />

which limits <strong>the</strong> integrati<strong>on</strong> process<br />

within <strong>the</strong> bounds of each government.<br />

This lack of instituti<strong>on</strong>s has several<br />

implicati<strong>on</strong>s, including <strong>the</strong> vagueness of<br />

rules and regulati<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>trolling trade.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, such instituti<strong>on</strong>s would have<br />

<strong>the</strong> authority to settle disputes and c<strong>on</strong>flicts<br />

arising between countries, especially<br />

that some of <strong>the</strong> MPs are not members<br />

of <strong>the</strong> World Trade Organizati<strong>on</strong><br />

(WTO), namely Algeria, <strong>the</strong> Palestinian<br />

Authority, and Leban<strong>on</strong>. Hence, violati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

by or against <strong>the</strong>se countries,<br />

such as those enacted between Egypt<br />

and Leban<strong>on</strong>, are resolved bilaterally in<br />

Figure 11: Shares of Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Sectors to GDP in a Sample of Arab Countries<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong> Study FEM22-07, from World Bank, WDI 2003


an inefficient way, which often requires<br />

political interventi<strong>on</strong>. These c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

ultimately weaken trade ties between<br />

<strong>the</strong>se countries and represent fur<strong>the</strong>r<br />

obstructi<strong>on</strong> to regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The most recent RTA in <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong><br />

is <strong>the</strong> Greater Arab Free Trade Area<br />

(GAFTA), which is specifically interested<br />

in <strong>the</strong> liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of trade in goods.<br />

It is planned that through <strong>the</strong> GAFTA,<br />

a customs uni<strong>on</strong> will be formed am<strong>on</strong>g<br />

member countries over a period of<br />

ten years, starting in 2006. Analysts<br />

see GAFTA as <strong>the</strong> first true integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

agreement. It is believed that GAFTA will<br />

outperform its predecessors. To avoid<br />

falling into <strong>the</strong> traps of ineffectiveness,<br />

as has always been <strong>the</strong> case with<br />

Arab RTAs, implementati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> GAFTA<br />

agreement should build <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> less<strong>on</strong>s<br />

learned from successful experiences,<br />

such as that of <strong>the</strong> EU.<br />

The EU has had several advantages<br />

and strengths that have supported its<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong>. Firstly, and most<br />

importantly, <strong>the</strong>re is a clear visi<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong> intended goals. For <strong>the</strong> EU, ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

integrati<strong>on</strong> is not <strong>the</strong> end, ra<strong>the</strong>r a<br />

means to achieving political integrati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

On <strong>the</strong> Arab fr<strong>on</strong>t, however, <strong>the</strong> goal is<br />

often not clear and, as previously menti<strong>on</strong>ed,<br />

is frequently vague and based <strong>on</strong><br />

emoti<strong>on</strong>al drives.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> EU has moved to a<br />

federal approach by creating supranati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

instituti<strong>on</strong>s that were granted <strong>the</strong><br />

power to oversee <strong>the</strong> process of integrati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Examples of <strong>the</strong>se instituti<strong>on</strong>s are<br />

<strong>the</strong> European Parliament, <strong>the</strong> European<br />

Court of Justice, <strong>the</strong> European Central<br />

Bank, and <strong>the</strong> European Commissi<strong>on</strong>. In<br />

<strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong>, however, integrati<strong>on</strong> is<br />

-69-<br />

still based <strong>on</strong> a governmental approach,<br />

mainly due to <strong>the</strong> fact that political leaders<br />

fear <strong>the</strong> loss of <strong>the</strong>ir sovereignty<br />

and authority.<br />

Moreover, European agreements are<br />

mostly clear and specific with attainable<br />

goals. The EU has adopted a gradual and<br />

pragmatic approach that has enabled a<br />

smooth and affordable transformati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

moving steadily from a shallow type of<br />

integrati<strong>on</strong> to a deeper <strong>on</strong>e. Analysts<br />

argue, however, that recent development<br />

in internati<strong>on</strong>al trade and technological<br />

advancement would not enable<br />

<strong>the</strong> success and sustainability of a shallow<br />

integrati<strong>on</strong> approach.<br />

Going back to <strong>the</strong> initiati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> EU,<br />

two factors helped <strong>the</strong> integrati<strong>on</strong> process,<br />

<strong>on</strong>e of which is <strong>the</strong> pressure and<br />

support of <strong>the</strong> United States to push<br />

forward <strong>the</strong> process. In additi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> six<br />

founding countries of <strong>the</strong> EU had similar<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s. The difference<br />

between average n<strong>on</strong>-weighted tariff<br />

levels, for example, was around 10%<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly. On <strong>the</strong> Arab fr<strong>on</strong>t, however, as<br />

shown above, countries of <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong> are<br />

not homogeneous enough to allow for a<br />

smooth integrati<strong>on</strong> process.<br />

Competiti<strong>on</strong> Laws<br />

To complement and facilitate trade relati<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

competiti<strong>on</strong> laws have been initiated<br />

and fine-tuned worldwide. In<br />

<strong>2005</strong>, over 110 countries have embraced<br />

nati<strong>on</strong>al competiti<strong>on</strong> laws in order<br />

to prohibit anti-competitive behavior<br />

and to guarantee a competitive market.<br />

However, it has been proven that nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

competiti<strong>on</strong> laws are not sufficient<br />

to oversee competiti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

level. This argument is believed to be


true since objectives of different nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

competiti<strong>on</strong> laws may vary and because<br />

some countries entering regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

may not be operating under a<br />

nati<strong>on</strong>al competiti<strong>on</strong> law. Introducing<br />

a regi<strong>on</strong>al competiti<strong>on</strong> law necessitates<br />

<strong>the</strong> introducti<strong>on</strong> of a regi<strong>on</strong>al competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

authority.<br />

With respect to Arab integrati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> Arab<br />

League Charter of 1945 has not menti<strong>on</strong>ed<br />

<strong>the</strong> provisi<strong>on</strong> of a competiti<strong>on</strong> law. It<br />

is not clear whe<strong>the</strong>r this was a deliberate<br />

decisi<strong>on</strong> or whe<strong>the</strong>r it has been overlooked.<br />

It is suggested, however, that <strong>the</strong><br />

Charter unintenti<strong>on</strong>ally overlooked this<br />

noti<strong>on</strong>, especially that it was not widely<br />

publicized at <strong>the</strong> time. On <strong>the</strong> European<br />

side, however, competiti<strong>on</strong> laws have<br />

been initiated in Austria in 1890. Then,<br />

<strong>the</strong> first European competiti<strong>on</strong> law was<br />

adopted in Germany in 1923, and has<br />

been developing ever since. As <strong>the</strong><br />

GAFTA agreement is believed to allow<br />

for more integrati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong> is<br />

in need for a regi<strong>on</strong>al competiti<strong>on</strong> law.<br />

The EU experience would be a valuable<br />

less<strong>on</strong> to build <strong>on</strong>.<br />

One of <strong>the</strong> main objectives of <strong>the</strong><br />

European competiti<strong>on</strong> law was supporting<br />

<strong>the</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> of a single market.<br />

The process of enacting <strong>the</strong> law for <strong>the</strong><br />

EU was not effortless. Several obstacles<br />

have been overcome. Oppositi<strong>on</strong> of big<br />

industries was <strong>on</strong>e of <strong>the</strong>se obstacles;<br />

<strong>the</strong>se viewed <strong>the</strong> law as limiting. It<br />

has also faced political and intellectual<br />

resistance. It was primarily with <strong>the</strong><br />

persistence and determinati<strong>on</strong> of member<br />

states that this law saw <strong>the</strong> light. It<br />

had to change <strong>the</strong> perceived noti<strong>on</strong> that<br />

competiti<strong>on</strong> laws are a c<strong>on</strong>straint and<br />

plant <strong>the</strong> idea that it is a c<strong>on</strong>structive<br />

social power instead. Initially, European<br />

-70-<br />

agreements did not include competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

laws, but had <strong>the</strong> necessary provisi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

to enact <strong>on</strong>e. These provisi<strong>on</strong>s, as previously<br />

menti<strong>on</strong>ed, are lacking in <strong>the</strong><br />

case of <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, European bureaucrats were<br />

supportive of <strong>the</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> law, which<br />

facilitated <strong>the</strong> process of its enactment.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong>, however, bureaucrats<br />

lack a profound understanding of <strong>the</strong><br />

importance of a competiti<strong>on</strong> law to <strong>the</strong><br />

process of integrati<strong>on</strong>. It is suggested<br />

that a model competiti<strong>on</strong> law be formulated<br />

for <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong>, to serve as a<br />

guide for harm<strong>on</strong>izati<strong>on</strong> of nati<strong>on</strong>al competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

laws, which could pave <strong>the</strong> way<br />

for <strong>the</strong> passing of a regi<strong>on</strong>al competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

law.<br />

Public Finance C<strong>on</strong>vergence<br />

Ano<strong>the</strong>r aspect that is believed to be<br />

significant for deepening regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

is public finance c<strong>on</strong>vergence, as<br />

it is argued that discrepancy of member<br />

states’ fiscal policy may create political<br />

tensi<strong>on</strong> and disagreement. Gradual fiscal<br />

c<strong>on</strong>vergence may guarantee a smooth<br />

integrati<strong>on</strong> process and may minimize<br />

<strong>the</strong> costs incurred by member states.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, removal of barriers and<br />

distorti<strong>on</strong>s, especially tax coordinati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

is crucial for regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong>. Public<br />

finance c<strong>on</strong>vergence is even a pre-requisite<br />

for deeper forms of integrati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

specifically m<strong>on</strong>etary and fiscal uni<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Again, this c<strong>on</strong>vergence implies a unified<br />

authority, hence a supranati<strong>on</strong>al instituti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The EU experience is just as beneficial in<br />

<strong>the</strong> area of public finance c<strong>on</strong>vergence.<br />

The EU has realized that it is crucial<br />

to narrow <strong>the</strong> gap between richer and


poorer areas of <strong>the</strong> Uni<strong>on</strong>. Thus, it has<br />

adopted budgetary federalism to be able<br />

to cope with this challenge; especially<br />

that per capita income of <strong>the</strong> 15 initial<br />

members of <strong>the</strong> EU is between 2.2 and<br />

13 times that of <strong>the</strong> ten new members.<br />

The European Commissi<strong>on</strong> has put an<br />

acti<strong>on</strong> plan spanning <strong>the</strong> period 2006-<br />

2013 to narrow this gap. The plan has<br />

been allocated €336.4 billi<strong>on</strong>, divided<br />

am<strong>on</strong>g three main objectives. The first<br />

objective, which is assigned €262 billi<strong>on</strong>,<br />

will target underdeveloped areas, which<br />

have a GDP of less than 75% of <strong>the</strong><br />

EU average. The sec<strong>on</strong>d aim, which<br />

has been allotted a sum of €61 billi<strong>on</strong>,<br />

will target regi<strong>on</strong>s that are undertaking<br />

reforms. The third comp<strong>on</strong>ent of <strong>the</strong><br />

plan, with a budget of €13.4 billi<strong>on</strong>, will<br />

enhance trade am<strong>on</strong>g EU member states.<br />

This plan was presented in detail to<br />

give an idea of how regi<strong>on</strong>s tackle <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

disparities. Such a plan should be adopted<br />

with some modificati<strong>on</strong> to fit <strong>the</strong><br />

Arab situati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong>, similar disparities<br />

between countries as well as poverty<br />

problems exist. The level of domestic and<br />

foreign public debt, for example, is relatively<br />

high am<strong>on</strong>g some Arab countries.<br />

It is as high as 100% of GDP for Egypt,<br />

135% for Leban<strong>on</strong>, 93% for Jordan, and<br />

81% in <strong>the</strong> case of Syria. Moreover, <strong>the</strong><br />

discrepancy of public spending between<br />

member states is huge, especially that<br />

some countries direct a c<strong>on</strong>siderable<br />

amount of public spending to military<br />

expenditure.<br />

It should be acknowledged, however,<br />

that taxes have been featuring a declining<br />

trend in Arab countries. In additi<strong>on</strong>,<br />

by 2004, customs and duties am<strong>on</strong>g Arab<br />

countries have been reduced to 20% of<br />

-71-<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir level in 1997. Many countries have<br />

also started revising and restructuring<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir tax systems. However, reforms<br />

are d<strong>on</strong>e <strong>on</strong> a country basis ra<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>ally, which may result in widening<br />

<strong>the</strong> disparities.<br />

The problem with fiscal c<strong>on</strong>vergence is<br />

that states have to be willing to bear<br />

some short-term costs in order to reap<br />

l<strong>on</strong>g-term gains. In additi<strong>on</strong>, coordinati<strong>on</strong><br />

is a key issue. Individual reform<br />

might be even worse than existing disparities.<br />

M<strong>on</strong>etary Policy<br />

Moving from fiscal c<strong>on</strong>vergence, <strong>the</strong><br />

next step would be harm<strong>on</strong>izing m<strong>on</strong>etary<br />

policy. This topic cannot possibly be<br />

discussed without shedding light <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

unique experience of <strong>the</strong> EU. It is worth<br />

noting that <strong>the</strong> idea of a unified currency<br />

was met with great skepticism. This<br />

move required <strong>the</strong> willingness of political<br />

leaders, an effective regi<strong>on</strong>al instituti<strong>on</strong>al<br />

framework, and agreeing that <strong>on</strong>e of<br />

<strong>the</strong> member states would play a leading<br />

role in <strong>the</strong> process. In <strong>the</strong> case of The<br />

EU, Germany was <strong>the</strong> primary driving<br />

force. The Arab versi<strong>on</strong>, however, fails<br />

to fulfill <strong>the</strong>se three requirements. There<br />

are doubts about Arab leaders’ willingness<br />

to be involved in such deep integrati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

In The Arab world, integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

is merely a political slogan. Hence, it is<br />

difficult to have a regi<strong>on</strong>al instituti<strong>on</strong>al<br />

framework in such a hostile envir<strong>on</strong>ment.<br />

And certainly, choosing a leader<br />

would be <strong>the</strong> most difficult and ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

impossible task.<br />

Establishing <strong>the</strong> European Central Bank<br />

(ECB) was crucial for <strong>the</strong> success of this<br />

form of integrati<strong>on</strong>. It was a supranatio-


nal instituti<strong>on</strong> that possessed credibility,<br />

a suitable strategy, technical expertise,<br />

as well as <strong>the</strong> authority to implement its<br />

plans. A crucial pre-requisite for <strong>the</strong> success<br />

of <strong>the</strong> ECB was its independence. It<br />

is argued that independence of central<br />

banks implies lower inflati<strong>on</strong> rates and<br />

better growth and employment c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

The ECB also sustained transparency;<br />

although this is a difficult task, as<br />

any events that are unaccounted for and<br />

that may affect m<strong>on</strong>etary policy could<br />

attack its credibility. The process was<br />

accompanied by awareness campaigns<br />

to guarantee support of <strong>the</strong> public.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong>, most integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

attempts relied heavily <strong>on</strong> trade, which<br />

was sometimes followed by labor and<br />

capital mobility. However, not much<br />

effort has been exerted to identify regi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

m<strong>on</strong>etary policies.<br />

Box: South-South Financial and M<strong>on</strong>etary<br />

Integrati<strong>on</strong> (based <strong>on</strong> <strong>Femise</strong> study<br />

FEM22-39)<br />

MPCs are opting for increased regi<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

integrati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> future. An important<br />

part of ec<strong>on</strong>omic integrati<strong>on</strong> is <strong>the</strong> increase in<br />

cross border trade. However, given <strong>the</strong> unstable<br />

m<strong>on</strong>etary, macroec<strong>on</strong>omic and financial<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ments in certain parts of <strong>the</strong><br />

MED regi<strong>on</strong>, it is doubtful whe<strong>the</strong>r pursued<br />

macroec<strong>on</strong>omic policies will provide <strong>the</strong> required<br />

stability for increasing ec<strong>on</strong>omic integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>on</strong> a regi<strong>on</strong>al scale.<br />

We still see significant divergence in business<br />

cycles and exchange rate polices. The existence<br />

of exchange rate overvaluati<strong>on</strong>s and<br />

misalignments within GAFTA countries is still<br />

hindering intraregi<strong>on</strong>al trade flows. Therefore,<br />

macroec<strong>on</strong>omic policy divergence within <strong>the</strong><br />

regi<strong>on</strong> appears to be am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> main obstacles<br />

towards achieving fur<strong>the</strong>r trade and<br />

m<strong>on</strong>etary integrati<strong>on</strong>. One way to circumvent<br />

this problem is perhaps through <strong>the</strong> adopti<strong>on</strong><br />

of a comm<strong>on</strong> currency within <strong>the</strong> MED<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The exchange rate literature stipulates that <strong>the</strong><br />

benefits of m<strong>on</strong>etary unificati<strong>on</strong>, by adopting<br />

a comm<strong>on</strong> currency, are in <strong>the</strong> form of elimi-<br />

-72-<br />

nati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> costs associated with exchange<br />

rate misalignments and currency c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The recent GAFTA agreements do not immediately<br />

provide for labor mobility within <strong>the</strong><br />

regi<strong>on</strong> and for fiscal cross-border transfers<br />

in order to smooth out ec<strong>on</strong>omic and financial<br />

shocks. Fur<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> various MED central<br />

banks do not possess a good track record<br />

of maintaining price stability, and a flexible<br />

exchange rate, which allows <strong>the</strong>m to pursue<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir own independent m<strong>on</strong>etary policy. A<br />

m<strong>on</strong>etary policy that adopts a comm<strong>on</strong> currency<br />

or that ties <strong>the</strong> various MED currencies<br />

closely to <strong>the</strong> <strong>euro</strong> and not <strong>the</strong> dollar can turn<br />

out to be instrumental in borrowing m<strong>on</strong>etary<br />

credibility from <strong>the</strong> European Central Bank<br />

(ECB), and thus, may reduce <strong>the</strong> MED regi<strong>on</strong><br />

inflati<strong>on</strong> and interest rates.<br />

If <strong>the</strong>re is a desire for m<strong>on</strong>etary independence,<br />

<strong>the</strong>n a flexible exchange rate regime<br />

is better for MED countries in <strong>the</strong> presence of<br />

structural differences between <strong>the</strong> different<br />

MED countries. However, Leban<strong>on</strong>, Egypt,<br />

Morocco and Tunisia’s experience with flexible<br />

rates has been disappointing, given <strong>the</strong> high<br />

volatility of <strong>the</strong>ir real exchange rates and <strong>the</strong><br />

prol<strong>on</strong>ged misalignment of <strong>the</strong>ir respective<br />

currencies from its equilibrium value. A weak<br />

domestic currency c<strong>on</strong>tributes to <strong>the</strong> low<br />

productivity of domestic firms competing in<br />

<strong>the</strong> foreign sector. Since <strong>the</strong>se countries are<br />

moving toward greater trade links with each<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r, greater exchange rate fixity vis-à-vis<br />

<strong>the</strong> Euro might be favored.<br />

The <strong>Femise</strong> study analysis is based <strong>on</strong> yearly<br />

data for <strong>the</strong> period 1960-2003, collected from<br />

<strong>the</strong> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Financial Statistics database,<br />

and <strong>the</strong> Arab M<strong>on</strong>etary Fund to study <strong>the</strong><br />

status of m<strong>on</strong>etary integrati<strong>on</strong> within <strong>the</strong> MED<br />

regi<strong>on</strong> and <strong>the</strong> prospects for <strong>the</strong> adopti<strong>on</strong> of a<br />

comm<strong>on</strong> currency.<br />

Cointegrati<strong>on</strong> tests were used to study South-<br />

South m<strong>on</strong>etary integrati<strong>on</strong> to see whe<strong>the</strong>r<br />

<strong>the</strong> MPCs set <strong>the</strong>ir macro and m<strong>on</strong>etary policies<br />

independently, or follow some sort of<br />

policy c<strong>on</strong>vergence, and can <strong>the</strong>refore adopt<br />

a comm<strong>on</strong> currency. The South-South cointegrati<strong>on</strong><br />

results show that <strong>the</strong>re is no c<strong>on</strong>vergence<br />

in MED m<strong>on</strong>etary or macroec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

policies in general. The results of <strong>the</strong> test<br />

pointed towards a str<strong>on</strong>g l<strong>on</strong>g-run relati<strong>on</strong>ship<br />

between <strong>the</strong> GDP growth rates of Jordan<br />

Kuwait, Morocco, Saudi Arabia, Syria, Tunisia,<br />

UAE, and Leban<strong>on</strong>, indicating a str<strong>on</strong>g c<strong>on</strong>vergence<br />

in MED business cycles. While this can<br />

perhaps be explained by <strong>the</strong> fact that greater<br />

trade links resulting from GAFTA are gradually


leading to similar dynamics of <strong>the</strong> rates of<br />

growth of GDP, <strong>the</strong>se GDP growth rates are<br />

highly correlated with oil price fluctuati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

This is not <strong>on</strong>ly true for <strong>the</strong> oil producing MED<br />

countries, but also true for <strong>the</strong> remaining<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-oil producing MED countries through <strong>the</strong><br />

significant effects of workers remittances working<br />

in oil-MED countries. One can thus safely<br />

c<strong>on</strong>clude that <strong>the</strong> str<strong>on</strong>g c<strong>on</strong>vergence in <strong>the</strong><br />

rate of growth of GDP is not really <strong>the</strong> result<br />

of greater trade integrati<strong>on</strong>, but is ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

driven by <strong>the</strong> dynamics of oil prices. The cointegrati<strong>on</strong><br />

results for nominal exchange rates<br />

in Jordan, Egypt, Kuwait, Morocco, Syria,<br />

Tunisia, and <strong>the</strong> UAE points to a ra<strong>the</strong>r weak<br />

c<strong>on</strong>vergence, which is not surprising. It is<br />

attributed to <strong>the</strong> lack of coordinati<strong>on</strong> of m<strong>on</strong>etary<br />

and exchange rate polices, and to <strong>the</strong><br />

fact that <strong>the</strong>re is a significant degree of heterogeneity<br />

in MED exchange rates policies: at<br />

least 5 of <strong>the</strong> seven MED countries appear to<br />

be setting <strong>the</strong>ir exchange rates independently.<br />

The result of test for cointegrati<strong>on</strong> between<br />

<strong>the</strong> inflati<strong>on</strong> rates of Bahrain, Egypt, Jordan,<br />

Saudi Arabia and Syria points to <strong>the</strong> existence<br />

of a very weak c<strong>on</strong>vergence of MED m<strong>on</strong>etary<br />

policies with respect to inflati<strong>on</strong>. The presences<br />

of a c<strong>on</strong>vergence in government m<strong>on</strong>etary<br />

policies cannot be attributed to more coordinati<strong>on</strong><br />

in MED m<strong>on</strong>etary polices, but is ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

due <strong>the</strong> fact that all MPCs have been devoting<br />

significant efforts to c<strong>on</strong>tain <strong>the</strong> inflati<strong>on</strong>ary<br />

pressures of <strong>the</strong> late 1980s.<br />

The general c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> drawn is that macroec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

and m<strong>on</strong>etary policy coordinati<strong>on</strong><br />

is still lacking in <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong> and more efforts<br />

need to be devoted in that respect. One area<br />

where genuine efforts should be devoted relates<br />

to government M<strong>on</strong>etary policies. There is<br />

a need for more harm<strong>on</strong>izati<strong>on</strong> of exchange<br />

rate and interest rate policies. The policies<br />

of fixed exchange rates to <strong>the</strong> USD have led<br />

to real exchange rate overvaluati<strong>on</strong>s with<br />

detrimental impacts <strong>on</strong> intra-regi<strong>on</strong>al trade.<br />

Two policy opti<strong>on</strong>s are available. The optimal<br />

m<strong>on</strong>etary policy opti<strong>on</strong> is a m<strong>on</strong>etary uni<strong>on</strong><br />

between those countries. However, since a<br />

m<strong>on</strong>etary uni<strong>on</strong> between GAFTA members is<br />

a somewhat distant prospect, <strong>the</strong>se countries<br />

should perhaps follow <strong>the</strong> Egyptian Tunisian<br />

and Moroccan examples and introduce in <strong>the</strong><br />

short run more flexibility in <strong>the</strong>ir exchange<br />

rates. In <strong>the</strong> l<strong>on</strong>g-run <strong>the</strong>se countries can<br />

opt for more fixity through a rigid peg or an<br />

exchange rate target z<strong>on</strong>e as a preliminary<br />

step before <strong>the</strong> adopti<strong>on</strong> of a comm<strong>on</strong> currency.<br />

However, this may not be a viable<br />

alternative for <strong>the</strong> majority of <strong>the</strong> MPCs, given<br />

<strong>the</strong> virtual absence of independent m<strong>on</strong>etary<br />

-73-<br />

policies and well-developed capital markets.<br />

Ano<strong>the</strong>r c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> is that underdeveloped<br />

m<strong>on</strong>etary, political and policy-making instituti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

tend to undermine <strong>the</strong> effectiveness<br />

of discreti<strong>on</strong>ary m<strong>on</strong>etary policy. For now,<br />

some type of fixed arrangement may be <strong>the</strong><br />

safest opti<strong>on</strong> for most of <strong>the</strong>se countries. For<br />

<strong>the</strong> MED countries engaged in a significant<br />

amount of trade with <strong>the</strong> EU, a <strong>euro</strong> peg may<br />

be more appropriate than a dollar peg. In<br />

all cases, those countries maintaining fixed<br />

exchange rate arrangements must implement<br />

crisis-preventi<strong>on</strong> measures, namely by exercising<br />

fiscal discipline, managing <strong>the</strong>ir debts<br />

and foreign reserves, and avoiding currency<br />

appreciati<strong>on</strong>. As <strong>the</strong> countries in <strong>the</strong> MED<br />

regi<strong>on</strong> improve <strong>the</strong>ir m<strong>on</strong>etary and fiscal<br />

infrastructures and become more integrated<br />

with global capital markets, <strong>the</strong>y should altoge<strong>the</strong>r<br />

adopt a comm<strong>on</strong> currency in <strong>the</strong> l<strong>on</strong>g<br />

run.<br />

Agricultural issues<br />

When c<strong>on</strong>sidering integrati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

Arab regi<strong>on</strong>, special attenti<strong>on</strong> should<br />

be paid to <strong>the</strong> agricultural sector, as it<br />

is <strong>on</strong>e of <strong>the</strong> major sectors of <strong>the</strong> Arab<br />

world. Around 23 milli<strong>on</strong> workers are<br />

employed in direct agricultural activities<br />

in <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>. Yet, despite <strong>the</strong> vast<br />

natural resources available in <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>,<br />

<strong>the</strong> absence of policies and regulati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

have led to a large and widening trade<br />

gap in that sector. The majority of Arab<br />

countries import agricultural products<br />

intensively. Over <strong>the</strong> period 1980-2003,<br />

agricultural imports of <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong><br />

increased from US$19 billi<strong>on</strong> to US$26.2<br />

billi<strong>on</strong>. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, exports<br />

increased from US$3 billi<strong>on</strong> to <strong>on</strong>ly<br />

US$5.7 billi<strong>on</strong> (Figure 12). With respect<br />

to trade am<strong>on</strong>g Arab countries, its volume<br />

amounted to US$5.3 billi<strong>on</strong>, which<br />

implies that imports from within <strong>the</strong><br />

Arab regi<strong>on</strong> represents <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>e fourth<br />

of total imports of Arab countries.<br />

On <strong>the</strong> European side of <strong>the</strong> world, <strong>the</strong><br />

number of workers employed in <strong>the</strong> agri


cultural sector dropped from 19 milli<strong>on</strong><br />

in 1970 to <strong>on</strong>ly 6.7 in 2002. This drop<br />

could be attributed to several factors,<br />

including <strong>the</strong> growth of <strong>the</strong> industrial<br />

and services sectors, representing a pull<br />

factor, and <strong>the</strong> increasing mechanizati<strong>on</strong><br />

of agricultural processes. The agricultural<br />

sector of both <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong> and<br />

<strong>the</strong> EU has two specific differences. First,<br />

its c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to GDP is much lower for<br />

EU countries. In additi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> structure<br />

of agricultural producti<strong>on</strong> is quite different,<br />

represented by, <strong>the</strong> quality of producti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

<strong>the</strong> level of mechanizati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong><br />

scale of business, etc. To illustrate <strong>the</strong><br />

difference, it is interesting to see that<br />

<strong>the</strong> highest level of exports per laborer<br />

in <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong> was reached in <strong>the</strong><br />

year 2002. Yet it represented <strong>on</strong>ly 10%<br />

of that of <strong>the</strong> EU in <strong>the</strong> same year. While<br />

<strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong> is still struggling through<br />

<strong>the</strong> trade liberalizati<strong>on</strong> stage, <strong>the</strong> EU has<br />

already proceeded to full integrati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Despite <strong>the</strong> fact that agriculture accounts<br />

<strong>on</strong> average for <strong>on</strong>ly 2% of EU countries,<br />

its development and integrati<strong>on</strong> have<br />

been paid special attenti<strong>on</strong> by <strong>the</strong> EU. The<br />

EU has initiated <strong>the</strong> Comm<strong>on</strong> Agricultural<br />

-74-<br />

Policy (CAP) with <strong>the</strong> aim of increasing<br />

agricultural productivity, guaranteeing a<br />

decent standard of living for <strong>the</strong> agricultural<br />

community, stabilizing <strong>the</strong> market,<br />

ensuring <strong>the</strong> availability of supplies,<br />

and maintaining reas<strong>on</strong>able prices. As a<br />

result of this policy, cereal producti<strong>on</strong>, for<br />

example, has boomed in Europe since <strong>the</strong><br />

nineties. The EU has also worked <strong>on</strong> narrowing<br />

<strong>the</strong> trade gap between its imports<br />

and exports (Figure 13).<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, while <strong>the</strong> Arab intra-trade<br />

is quite limited, as displayed above, <strong>the</strong><br />

EU depends more <strong>on</strong> intra-markets than<br />

<strong>on</strong> external <strong>on</strong>es. Figure 14 portrays<br />

<strong>the</strong> proporti<strong>on</strong> of European intra-trade<br />

to total trade. The figures represented<br />

here pertain to <strong>the</strong> EU 15 <strong>on</strong>ly, which<br />

suggests that <strong>the</strong> EU enlargement to<br />

include 25 states would even increase<br />

<strong>the</strong> proporti<strong>on</strong> of intra-trade.<br />

The weak integrati<strong>on</strong> of agriculture has<br />

been attributed to several factors. One<br />

of <strong>the</strong> main reas<strong>on</strong>s is importing cheap<br />

products from outside <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Ano<strong>the</strong>r reas<strong>on</strong> is investments that are<br />

directed to large public works projects.<br />

Figure 12: Imports and Exports of Total Agricultural Products in <strong>the</strong> Arab Regi<strong>on</strong><br />

1980-2003 (US$1000)<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong> study FEM22-07


These projects often need high main-<br />

tenance costs, which leaves countries<br />

with little funds to be directed towards<br />

developing <strong>the</strong> agricultural sector and<br />

adopting new technologies. A factor that<br />

is comm<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g all aspects of integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

is <strong>the</strong> lack of regi<strong>on</strong>al agricultural<br />

policies.<br />

To combat <strong>the</strong> weaknesses of <strong>the</strong> agricultural<br />

sector, several Arab instituti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

have paid special attenti<strong>on</strong> to its<br />

development allover <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>. One<br />

example is <strong>the</strong> Arab Fund for Ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

-75-<br />

and Social Development. From 1974 to<br />

2003, agricultural and rural development<br />

have been allocated an amount<br />

of KD886 milli<strong>on</strong>, representing around<br />

<strong>on</strong>e fifth of <strong>the</strong> Fund’s total loan commitments.<br />

The Kuwait Fund for Arab<br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Development has directed<br />

KD338 milli<strong>on</strong> to agriculture, which<br />

represent around 19% of total disbursements.<br />

The Saudi Fund for Development<br />

has also shown interest in <strong>the</strong> agricultural<br />

sector, directing around 19% of its<br />

disbursements to it, which amount to<br />

around SR4.5 billi<strong>on</strong> during <strong>the</strong> period<br />

Figure 13: EU agricultural imports and exports in milli<strong>on</strong> US$ (1980-2003)<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong> study FEM22-07<br />

Figure 14: Total EU trade in Agricultural Products including and Excluding Intra-<br />

Trade (1990-2003, milli<strong>on</strong> US$)<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong> study FEM22-07


1974-2003 in 71 projects. Although<br />

<strong>the</strong>se efforts have been widely appreciated,<br />

<strong>the</strong>y still fall short of providing<br />

a regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong> scheme and policies,<br />

as <strong>the</strong>y do not posses a supranati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

nature.<br />

Drawing <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> less<strong>on</strong>s learned from <strong>the</strong><br />

EU experience, <strong>the</strong>re is a str<strong>on</strong>g need<br />

for <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong> to adopt an agricultural<br />

model that would streng<strong>the</strong>n<br />

<strong>the</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong>, increase <strong>the</strong><br />

productivity of agricultural goods, and<br />

coordinate efforts between different<br />

member states. Arab countries need to<br />

start negotiating as <strong>on</strong>e entity in order<br />

to get better terms of trade and to be<br />

clearly heard internati<strong>on</strong>ally.<br />

Social Policies<br />

It is believed that integrati<strong>on</strong> would not<br />

be c<strong>on</strong>sidered successful, unless it truly<br />

benefits citizens of each of <strong>the</strong> member<br />

states. Thus, analysts are inclined to<br />

assess social policies as a measure of<br />

<strong>the</strong> extent of regi<strong>on</strong>al integrati<strong>on</strong> and<br />

<strong>the</strong> welfare of citizens.<br />

The Arab regi<strong>on</strong> is often characterized by<br />

<strong>the</strong> lack of coordinati<strong>on</strong> of social development<br />

efforts, not <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong> a regi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

level but even within each country.<br />

Development efforts are often carried<br />

out by individual NGOs. The regi<strong>on</strong> has<br />

witnessed incremental improvements in<br />

some of <strong>the</strong> social indices, such as<br />

maternal and infant mortality, life expectancy,<br />

and literacy rates, which will be<br />

discussed in detail <strong>the</strong>reafter. Yet <strong>the</strong><br />

Arab Human Development <str<strong>on</strong>g>Report</str<strong>on</strong>g> has<br />

stated that progress has been quite<br />

slow and cannot be seen as universal,<br />

as many citizens of <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong> are still<br />

deprived of <strong>the</strong>ir basic needs.<br />

-76-<br />

It is worth noting that <strong>the</strong> average<br />

per capita income PPP of Arab states<br />

is US$5,685. This is a relatively high<br />

value, when compared to <strong>the</strong> average of<br />

developing countries, which is US$4,359<br />

(2003 values, according to <strong>the</strong> Human<br />

Development <str<strong>on</strong>g>Report</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>2005</strong>). Yet this<br />

value is in a way misleading, as it is<br />

str<strong>on</strong>gly affected by values of <strong>the</strong> GCC<br />

countries, which have per capita incomes<br />

reaching up to US$22,420 for <strong>the</strong><br />

United Arab Emirates. O<strong>the</strong>r Arab states,<br />

however, have c<strong>on</strong>siderably lower<br />

values, such as Sudan (US$1,910) and<br />

Yemen (US$889).<br />

Despite apparent income improvements,<br />

some basic indices are still lagging<br />

behind. The Average literacy rate for <strong>the</strong><br />

Arab states is 64.1% while <strong>the</strong> developing<br />

countries’ average is 76.5%. The<br />

lowest rates of literacy in <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong> are<br />

to be found in Algeria, Egypt, Morocco,<br />

Oman, Sudan, Tunisia and Yemen, which<br />

also have lower incomes. Yet income is<br />

not <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly determinant of literacy. This<br />

hypo<strong>the</strong>sis is proven through a study<br />

comparing Oman and Jordan. While<br />

Oman’s per capita income is around<br />

triple that of Jordan, literacy rate of <strong>the</strong><br />

latter is higher than that of <strong>the</strong> former<br />

by around 20%.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> gender gap is a major<br />

characteristic in <strong>the</strong> Arab world. Literacy<br />

rates as well as labor force values prove<br />

that fact. Female literacy rates, as a<br />

percentage of males, accounts to 71%<br />

in <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>. In additi<strong>on</strong>, school registrati<strong>on</strong><br />

rates for females reach around<br />

83.8%, while <strong>the</strong> average of developing<br />

countries is 87.3%. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> rate<br />

of female ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity as a percentage<br />

of rates recorded for males reached<br />

38.9%. The narrowest gap of ec<strong>on</strong>omic


activity between males and females is<br />

found in Morocco, <strong>the</strong>n Kuwait, Tunisia,<br />

and Egypt, while <strong>the</strong> widest gap is recorded<br />

in Oman, Iraq, and Saudi Arabia. It<br />

should be recognized that, while female<br />

participati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> labor force increased<br />

by 11.7% in <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong> between<br />

1985 and 1997, <strong>the</strong> average increase<br />

for developing countries amounted to<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly 2.3%.<br />

On ano<strong>the</strong>r note, life expectancy has<br />

witnessed substantial improvements<br />

since <strong>the</strong> fifties, where it amounted to<br />

40.5 for males and 42.6 for females.<br />

During <strong>the</strong> period 1990-1995, life expectancy<br />

reached 62.6 and 65.2 for men<br />

and women, respectively. In additi<strong>on</strong>,<br />

under five mortality rates (per 1,000 live<br />

births) range from 3 to 39, with Leban<strong>on</strong><br />

reporting <strong>the</strong> lowest rate and Yemen <strong>the</strong><br />

highest. Maternal mortality rates (per<br />

100,000 live births) range between 3<br />

and 550. Total health expenditure as<br />

a percent of GDP ranges from 1.5 to<br />

10.1%.<br />

To improve <strong>the</strong> welfare of citizens, several<br />

Arab countries have established social<br />

funds, which act as mediators and deliver<br />

funds provided by <strong>the</strong> government<br />

as well as by d<strong>on</strong>ors to mainly <strong>the</strong> poor<br />

by financing small projects. They work<br />

<strong>on</strong> ensuring job opportunities, improving<br />

infrastructure, and offering basic<br />

services to <strong>the</strong> poor. Yet effectiveness<br />

of such funds can be hampered by a<br />

number of factors. The independence of<br />

such funds varies from <strong>on</strong>e nati<strong>on</strong> to <strong>the</strong><br />

o<strong>the</strong>r. While <strong>the</strong> Jordanian and Lebanese<br />

funds, for example, enjoy higher levels<br />

of independence, <strong>the</strong> board of directors<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Egyptian Social Fund is largely<br />

composed if government officials,<br />

which adds to its bureaucratic nature.<br />

-77-<br />

Moreover, m<strong>on</strong>itoring and evaluati<strong>on</strong><br />

of social funds’ activities are sometimes<br />

aband<strong>on</strong>ed with <strong>the</strong> intenti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

cutting costs. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> temporary<br />

nature of <strong>the</strong>se funds is a major<br />

challenge to <strong>the</strong> sustainability of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

interventi<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong> to <strong>the</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>al effort exerted<br />

in Arab countries, <strong>the</strong>re is a regi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

effort to improve <strong>the</strong> welfare of citizens.<br />

Just as in <strong>the</strong> case of agriculture displayed<br />

in <strong>the</strong> previous secti<strong>on</strong>, different<br />

instituti<strong>on</strong>s, such as <strong>the</strong> Arab Fund for<br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>omic and Social Development have<br />

paid special attenti<strong>on</strong> to social development.<br />

The fund has been directing almost<br />

9.3% of its total loan disbursements to<br />

social services projects. The Arab Reform<br />

Forum is yet ano<strong>the</strong>r attempt to harm<strong>on</strong>ize<br />

social policies. The forum has been<br />

established <strong>on</strong> 2004 in <strong>the</strong> Biblio<strong>the</strong>ca<br />

Alexandrina with <strong>the</strong> mandate of c<strong>on</strong>tinuous<br />

dialogue between intellectuals.<br />

These dialogues are intended to discuss<br />

development issues, while particularly<br />

focusing <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> role of youth and women<br />

in development.<br />

Yet social policies in <strong>the</strong> Arab world are<br />

still lagging behind. This may be attributed<br />

to several hindrances. Political<br />

tensi<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong> has forced governments<br />

to direct large amounts of funds<br />

to military development, which is to <strong>the</strong><br />

disadvantage of social development.<br />

Thus <strong>the</strong>re is also a problem of unavailability<br />

of funds. High populati<strong>on</strong> growth<br />

rates are also a serious challenge, which<br />

also raises <strong>the</strong> issue of unemployment<br />

and <strong>the</strong> failure in many instances to provide<br />

professi<strong>on</strong>al training. The inability of<br />

coordinating development efforts am<strong>on</strong>g<br />

governments and different n<strong>on</strong>-governmental<br />

entities also hampers <strong>the</strong>ir effec-


tiveness; especially that civil society in<br />

Arab regi<strong>on</strong> has a limited experience.<br />

Centralizing decisi<strong>on</strong>-making is also an<br />

obstacle, especially given high rates of<br />

corrupti<strong>on</strong> and lack of capacity-building.<br />

The crisis management nature of most<br />

development efforts lacks sustainability<br />

and true welfare improvement.<br />

Moving to <strong>the</strong> European experience, it<br />

is worth noting that <strong>the</strong> European Social<br />

Fund has played <strong>on</strong>ly a marginal role in<br />

<strong>the</strong> integrati<strong>on</strong> of social policy. On ano<strong>the</strong>r<br />

fr<strong>on</strong>t, <strong>the</strong> European Social Charter<br />

of 1961, which was revised and extended<br />

in 1996, represents a set of binding<br />

undertakings. In additi<strong>on</strong>, to streng<strong>the</strong>n<br />

<strong>the</strong> role integrated social policy, <strong>the</strong><br />

European Court if Justice has limited<br />

a country’s c<strong>on</strong>trol over social policy<br />

in <strong>the</strong> sense that it has prohibited <strong>the</strong><br />

restricti<strong>on</strong> social benefits to a country’s<br />

citizens.<br />

One of <strong>the</strong> challenges that <strong>the</strong> EU had<br />

to deal with was <strong>the</strong> persistent unemployment<br />

of <strong>the</strong> nineties. To deal with<br />

such problem, each member state was<br />

required to formulate an acti<strong>on</strong> plan.<br />

Plans of all countries would <strong>the</strong>n be<br />

coordinated through <strong>the</strong> EU’s different<br />

bodies. The European Social Fund was<br />

to provide support to <strong>the</strong>se initiatives.<br />

This is just <strong>on</strong>e problem to dem<strong>on</strong>strate<br />

how <strong>the</strong> EU has been coordinating social<br />

development efforts.<br />

To accelerate <strong>the</strong> development process,<br />

Arab countries need to utilize <strong>the</strong> available<br />

resources efficiently and coordinate<br />

social development efforts. The two<br />

main problems of social development,<br />

namely youth unemployment and <strong>the</strong><br />

gender gap, need also to be addressed.<br />

To support development efforts, partici-<br />

-78-<br />

pati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> civil society must be fur<strong>the</strong>r<br />

encouraged and enhanced.<br />

Labor Mobility<br />

The shallowest form of integrati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

namely RTAs, c<strong>on</strong>centrate mainly <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

free movement of goods and services.<br />

Comm<strong>on</strong> markets, as <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>on</strong>d stage<br />

of integrati<strong>on</strong>, allow for <strong>the</strong> movement<br />

of factors of producti<strong>on</strong>, hence labour<br />

mobility. It is well known that labour<br />

mobility is a natural process that accompanies<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. However, it can<br />

be enhanced through fur<strong>the</strong>r integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

policies. Hence, in <strong>the</strong> absence of such<br />

policies, which is <strong>the</strong> case in <strong>the</strong> Arab<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>, pull factors are <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly determinant<br />

of labour mobility. Bilateral agreements<br />

are <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly agreements in <strong>the</strong><br />

Arab regi<strong>on</strong> that deal with some aspects<br />

of labour mobility, however, not to <strong>the</strong><br />

extent of its free movement.<br />

Egypt, for example, has signed agreements<br />

<strong>on</strong> cooperati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> labour issues<br />

with nine Arab countries during <strong>the</strong><br />

period 1974-1990. Morocco has agreements<br />

with five Arab countries, dating<br />

back to <strong>the</strong> early 1980s, Tunisia with<br />

four countries, and <strong>the</strong> United Arab<br />

Emirates with five countries. Despite<br />

this number of bilateral agreements,<br />

Arab labour force has been facing competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

from extra-regi<strong>on</strong>al labour,<br />

especially from Asia. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, political<br />

tensi<strong>on</strong> between Arab countries<br />

often resulted in <strong>the</strong> terminati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

employment of labourers of o<strong>the</strong>r Arab<br />

countries. This was not a unique event;<br />

it was repeated in several countries with<br />

large numbers of workers. In 1985, for<br />

example, Libya terminated <strong>the</strong> working<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tracts of large numbers of Egyptian<br />

and Tunisian migrant workers. Qatar


deported hundreds of Egyptian workers<br />

in 1998. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>on</strong>d Gulf<br />

war, in 1990-91, resulted in returning<br />

around 390 thousand Egyptian workers<br />

to <strong>the</strong>ir country. Estimates also suggest<br />

that GCC countries, as a result of disagreement<br />

<strong>on</strong> political stance pursued by<br />

<strong>the</strong>se countries during that war, deported<br />

over a milli<strong>on</strong> workers to Jordan,<br />

Syria, and Yemen.<br />

The Arab Labour Organisati<strong>on</strong> has adopted<br />

two charters to regulate labour<br />

movement within <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong>. They<br />

indicate that preference should be given<br />

to Arab workers, especially Palestinians,<br />

after preserving job opportunities for<br />

citizens of a member state. However,<br />

<strong>the</strong>y do not menti<strong>on</strong> anything about free<br />

labour mobility. In additi<strong>on</strong>, this is a n<strong>on</strong>binding<br />

instrument. The latest agreement<br />

in this respect is <strong>the</strong> Declarati<strong>on</strong><br />

of Principles <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> Facilitati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

Movement of Arab Labor, enacted in<br />

February <strong>2005</strong>. This declarati<strong>on</strong> menti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly <strong>the</strong> facilitati<strong>on</strong>, and not <strong>the</strong><br />

freeing, of labor movement. This too, is<br />

a n<strong>on</strong>-binding agreement.<br />

As previously indicated, in <strong>the</strong> absence<br />

of labour movement policies, ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

growth is <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly determinant of migrati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Within <strong>the</strong> Arab regi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> main<br />

pull factors exist in <strong>the</strong> GCC countries,<br />

as <strong>the</strong>y possess a huge potential of<br />

growth. Over <strong>the</strong> period 1975-2002, <strong>the</strong><br />

populati<strong>on</strong> of GCC receiving countries<br />

increased by 335%, namely from 9.7 to<br />

32.5 milli<strong>on</strong>. However, while <strong>the</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

populati<strong>on</strong> represented 77.4% of<br />

total populati<strong>on</strong> in 1975, it represented<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly 61.5% in 2002; implying a growth<br />

rate of migrant populati<strong>on</strong> of 568%.<br />

Yet <strong>the</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-GCC Arab porti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

migrant populati<strong>on</strong> decreased from 72%<br />

-79-<br />

in 1975 to 31% in 1996. Specifically in<br />

Saudi Arabia, which is <strong>the</strong> most striking<br />

example, <strong>the</strong> porti<strong>on</strong> moved from 90%<br />

to <strong>on</strong>ly 30%.<br />

To <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>trary, <strong>the</strong> EU has solid integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

policies with respect to labour<br />

mobility. Citizens of EU members have<br />

<strong>the</strong> right to reside and be employed in<br />

any o<strong>the</strong>r member state. One of <strong>the</strong><br />

major obstacles that faced this form of<br />

integrati<strong>on</strong> was <strong>the</strong> divergence of qualificati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

To overcome this challenge, it<br />

was agreed that member states would<br />

mutually recognize each o<strong>the</strong>r’s qualificati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

instead of unifying <strong>the</strong> criteria<br />

for educati<strong>on</strong>. It is important to realize<br />

<strong>the</strong> difference between <strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong><br />

Arab regi<strong>on</strong> and that of <strong>the</strong> EU. While <strong>the</strong><br />

former did not have a clear visi<strong>on</strong> and<br />

determinati<strong>on</strong> to reach it, <strong>the</strong> latter established<br />

precise rules and regulati<strong>on</strong>s and<br />

delegated <strong>the</strong> authority of implementing<br />

<strong>the</strong>m to supranati<strong>on</strong>al instituti<strong>on</strong>s to<br />

guarantee <strong>the</strong>ir timely attainment.<br />

Looking Ahead<br />

The Arab regi<strong>on</strong> has a number of advantages<br />

that are of major value. Countries<br />

of <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong> have a str<strong>on</strong>g comm<strong>on</strong><br />

historical, cultural, and religious heritage,<br />

in additi<strong>on</strong> to being unified through<br />

<strong>on</strong>e language. The latter has been<br />

unavailable am<strong>on</strong>g EU member states.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong> enjoys a variety<br />

and wealth of natural resources. A collective<br />

populati<strong>on</strong> exceeding 270 milli<strong>on</strong><br />

in 2003 represents a huge market and a<br />

diverse labor force. The regi<strong>on</strong>’s locati<strong>on</strong><br />

in <strong>the</strong> heart of <strong>the</strong> world is also a great<br />

asset. Yet <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong> seems paralyzed<br />

as a result of several factors, notably a<br />

lack of commitment for integrati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> part of <strong>the</strong> member states.


The discussi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> different aspects of<br />

integrati<strong>on</strong> and less<strong>on</strong>s learned from <strong>the</strong><br />

European experience has shown a comm<strong>on</strong><br />

set of acti<strong>on</strong>s needed to actually<br />

reach proper integrati<strong>on</strong>. First, countries<br />

of <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong> need to have a clear visi<strong>on</strong><br />

of what <strong>the</strong>y really want to achieve.<br />

There is also a str<strong>on</strong>g need for political<br />

leaders to have <strong>the</strong> will and <strong>the</strong> commitment<br />

for integrati<strong>on</strong>; <strong>the</strong> lack <strong>the</strong>reof is<br />

a major hindrance. Countries also need<br />

to coordinate <strong>the</strong>ir efforts in different<br />

fields in order to form a homogeneous<br />

regi<strong>on</strong> ra<strong>the</strong>r than being scattered and<br />

sometimes even c<strong>on</strong>tradicting. Yet <strong>the</strong><br />

most important measure that truly needs<br />

instant acti<strong>on</strong> is forming supranati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

instituti<strong>on</strong>s capable of m<strong>on</strong>itoring and<br />

overseeing progress made in different<br />

countries towards integrati<strong>on</strong>. Without<br />

<strong>the</strong>se instituti<strong>on</strong>s, Arab countries will<br />

not be able to seriously coordinate <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

efforts and guarantee implementati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong> agreed objectives. A pre-requisite<br />

for <strong>the</strong> formati<strong>on</strong> of such instituti<strong>on</strong>s is<br />

<strong>the</strong> political authorities’ readiness to be<br />

evaluated by regi<strong>on</strong>al instituti<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

3. Migrati<strong>on</strong>s in <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean:<br />

<strong>the</strong> road for Deeper integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

Migrati<strong>on</strong> within <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean<br />

basin is a l<strong>on</strong>g-established phenomen<strong>on</strong><br />

with deep historical and socio-political<br />

implicati<strong>on</strong>s. Recently, this issue has<br />

become a much complex and c<strong>on</strong>testable<br />

subject.<br />

The influence of migrati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> global<br />

development is c<strong>on</strong>siderable: c<strong>on</strong>siderable<br />

for <strong>the</strong> EU because it fills gaps in<br />

<strong>the</strong> employment market and increases<br />

<strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> workforce and thus <strong>the</strong><br />

number of taxpayers; positive for <strong>the</strong><br />

developing countries because it takes<br />

-80-<br />

some of <strong>the</strong> pressure off <strong>the</strong> domestic<br />

employment market, brings in far more<br />

foreign currency overall than is received<br />

in official aid, and enhances skills.<br />

With unemployment <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> rise in <strong>the</strong><br />

Mediterranean Partners’ (MPs) ec<strong>on</strong>omies,<br />

migrati<strong>on</strong> forms a window of<br />

opportunity to absorb part of excess<br />

labor. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, c<strong>on</strong>cerns over<br />

social cohesi<strong>on</strong> issues and illegal migrati<strong>on</strong><br />

in Europe have prevented accepting<br />

migrati<strong>on</strong> as a compensati<strong>on</strong> for <strong>the</strong><br />

slow growth of <strong>the</strong> labor force.<br />

Demographic C<strong>on</strong>trasts of<br />

Labor Market Trends within <strong>the</strong><br />

Mediterranean Basin<br />

The demographic situati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong><br />

Mediterranean Basin varies c<strong>on</strong>siderably.<br />

The populati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> EU is aging;<br />

total births (7.3 milli<strong>on</strong> per year) do not<br />

compensate for <strong>the</strong> deaths (8.1 milli<strong>on</strong><br />

per year) (<strong>Femise</strong>, 2003). Moreover,<br />

<strong>the</strong> average populati<strong>on</strong> growth rate for<br />

<strong>the</strong> EU was 0.3% in <strong>the</strong> period of 1990-<br />

2003 while it was 2.4% for <strong>the</strong> sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

countries, and estimates show that it will<br />

decline to 0% and 1.7% in <strong>the</strong> period of<br />

2003-2015 for Europe and MPs respectively<br />

(World Bank, <strong>2005</strong>).<br />

Nor<strong>the</strong>rn countries have a relatively<br />

older populati<strong>on</strong>; those of <strong>the</strong> South, a<br />

fairly young populati<strong>on</strong>. Children under<br />

<strong>the</strong> age 15 account for between 35 and<br />

40 per cent of <strong>the</strong> populati<strong>on</strong> of sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

countries (<strong>Femise</strong>, 2003). Hence, <strong>the</strong><br />

proporti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> populati<strong>on</strong> of working<br />

age will grow more quickly than<br />

total populati<strong>on</strong>. Additi<strong>on</strong>al demand for<br />

employment will hence increase, as will<br />

<strong>the</strong> migratory potential. As a result,<br />

employment outside <strong>the</strong> domestic eco-


nomy has become a structural feature in<br />

many countries of <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Moreover, <strong>the</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Mediterranean<br />

populati<strong>on</strong> and <strong>the</strong> entrants to <strong>the</strong> labor<br />

markets will c<strong>on</strong>tinue to grow at least till<br />

2015, because <strong>the</strong> populati<strong>on</strong> structure<br />

is marked by <strong>the</strong> predominance of youth<br />

(FEMISE, 2003). Also, <strong>the</strong> average unemployment<br />

rate for <strong>the</strong> EU is 6.7% (ILO,<br />

2004a) while it is about 16.0% for <strong>the</strong><br />

South Med countries (World Bank, <strong>2005</strong>).<br />

Meanwhile, <strong>the</strong> European Uni<strong>on</strong> countries,<br />

faced with aging populati<strong>on</strong>s, are<br />

reluctant toward recognizing <strong>the</strong> need<br />

for managed and legal immigrati<strong>on</strong> programs<br />

to cover <strong>the</strong>ir labor requirements<br />

in <strong>the</strong> future.<br />

Migrati<strong>on</strong> Magnitude: Half of <strong>the</strong><br />

MPs’ migrants are bound to Europe<br />

South Med countries now form a major<br />

regi<strong>on</strong> of emigrati<strong>on</strong>. There are 2 main<br />

streams of emigrati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> MPs, <strong>on</strong>e<br />

bound for <strong>the</strong> Gulf Cooperati<strong>on</strong> Council<br />

countries (GCC) and <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r is bound<br />

for European countries. With a number<br />

of first-generati<strong>on</strong> emigrants ranging<br />

between 10 and 15 milli<strong>on</strong> according<br />

to whe<strong>the</strong>r migrants are counted by<br />

destinati<strong>on</strong> of countries of origin, First<br />

-81-<br />

generati<strong>on</strong> emigrants from <strong>the</strong> ten South<br />

Med countries appear to represent some<br />

4.8% of <strong>the</strong>ir aggregated populati<strong>on</strong><br />

which amounted to 260 milli<strong>on</strong> in <strong>2005</strong>.<br />

(Fargue, <strong>2005</strong>).<br />

Migrati<strong>on</strong> flows to <strong>the</strong> GCC countries<br />

This stream is directed towards <strong>the</strong> oilrich<br />

countries of Bahrain, Kuwait, Oman,<br />

Qatar, Saudi Arabia and <strong>the</strong> United Arab<br />

Emirates. These countries now have<br />

massive stocks of foreign labor, but<br />

immigrati<strong>on</strong> into <strong>the</strong>m related to development<br />

of oil resources back to 1972<br />

where about 800.000 migrant workers<br />

were settled in <strong>the</strong> GCC. With <strong>the</strong> oil prices<br />

increases which followed, <strong>the</strong> entire<br />

regi<strong>on</strong> rapidly became dependent up<strong>on</strong><br />

foreign labor, and by 1975 <strong>the</strong> foreign<br />

populati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> GCC states could have<br />

been as much as 3.8 milli<strong>on</strong> people, or<br />

40% of total populati<strong>on</strong><br />

Nowadays, expatriate workers represent<br />

almost three quarters of <strong>the</strong> labor force<br />

(Fasano, and, Rishi, 2004). A wide difference<br />

in <strong>the</strong> expatriate workers distributi<strong>on</strong><br />

am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> GCC countries exists,<br />

for while <strong>the</strong>y represent almost 90 per<br />

cent in <strong>the</strong> labor force of <strong>the</strong> UAE, <strong>the</strong>y<br />

account for up to 50 per cent in Saudi<br />

Arabia (table X19).<br />

Table X19: Percentage of nati<strong>on</strong>als and expatriates in <strong>the</strong> labour force of GCC countries,<br />

1995-2001 (000 Pers<strong>on</strong>)<br />

Total<br />

(‘000s)<br />

1995 * 2002**<br />

%<br />

Nati<strong>on</strong>als<br />

% N<strong>on</strong>nati<strong>on</strong>als<br />

Total<br />

(‘000s)<br />

%<br />

Nati<strong>on</strong>als<br />

% N<strong>on</strong>nati<strong>on</strong>als<br />

UAE 955,1 11,6 88,4 2 269,0 10,2 89,8<br />

Bahrain 226,5 40,0 60,0 308,3 40,1 59,0<br />

KSA 6 450,0 36,5 63,5 6 089,8*** 49,7 50,3<br />

Oman 670,3 35,8 64,2 731,5 21,7 78,2<br />

Qatar 218,0 17,9 82,1 322,9 14,2 85,7<br />

Kuwait 1 051,5 16,6 83,4 1 320,2 19,6 80,4<br />

Total 9 571,4 26,4 73,6 11 041,7 26,0 74,0<br />

Sources : * Maurice Girgis, Les nati<strong>on</strong>aux et les ouvriers migrants dans le GCC : Coping with Change,<br />

2000 ; ** GCC, STATISTICAL BULLETIN, volume 12, 2003; http : // www.gcc-sg.org/gccstatvo112/genstat/g4.htm;<br />

*** Annuaire d’OIT de Statistique du Travail 2002


As of mid 1980s to mid 1990s <strong>the</strong> GCC<br />

witnessed a substituti<strong>on</strong> of Asian workers<br />

for <strong>the</strong> existing Arab workers and <strong>the</strong><br />

share of Arabs declined from 75% of <strong>the</strong><br />

foreign workers in 1975 to 28% by 2000<br />

in favor of <strong>the</strong> Asian workers (Girgis,<br />

2002). One reas<strong>on</strong> for <strong>the</strong> decline is <strong>the</strong><br />

trend towards <strong>the</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>alizati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong><br />

labor markets. As <strong>the</strong> unemployment<br />

am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> GCC nati<strong>on</strong>als increased,<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir governments took measures which<br />

entailed adopting regulati<strong>on</strong>s limiting<br />

<strong>the</strong> size of foreign labor in favor of <strong>the</strong><br />

nati<strong>on</strong>al work force such as:<br />

√ Job reservati<strong>on</strong> where some professi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

are reserved <strong>on</strong>ly for nati<strong>on</strong>als.<br />

√ Subsidizing enterprises to increase<br />

<strong>the</strong> percentage of employed nati<strong>on</strong>als.<br />

Figure 15: MENA Migrants in <strong>the</strong> EU, by country of residence<br />

-82-<br />

√ Increasing <strong>the</strong> cost f foreign labor<br />

through taxati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

√ Relying <strong>on</strong> mandatory measures.<br />

These include quantitative targets<br />

or quotas <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> proporti<strong>on</strong><br />

of nati<strong>on</strong>als employed by private<br />

companies in specific professi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

or sectors.<br />

√ Attempting to equalize <strong>the</strong> perceived<br />

attractiveness of public and<br />

private employment by extending<br />

retirement benefits and social<br />

allowances to all nati<strong>on</strong>als independently<br />

of <strong>the</strong> sector that <strong>the</strong>y<br />

work for.<br />

√ Attempting to reduce <strong>the</strong> wage and<br />

productivity differential between<br />

<strong>the</strong> public and private sectors.<br />

Sources: Fargue, <strong>2005</strong>, based <strong>on</strong> calculati<strong>on</strong>s from:<br />

Algeria: 1998 populati<strong>on</strong> census; Armenia: 2001 populati<strong>on</strong> census; Australia: 2001 Populati<strong>on</strong> Census;<br />

Austria :Populati<strong>on</strong> census, 2001; Belgium: Office des étrangers, <strong>2005</strong>; Canada : 2001, Statistics<br />

Canada; Cyprus: Census of Populati<strong>on</strong>, 2002; Czech Republic: Ministry of <strong>the</strong> Interior, 2002; Denmark:<br />

Statistics Denmark, 2003; Est<strong>on</strong>ia: Populati<strong>on</strong> census, 2000; Finland: Statistics Finland, 2003; France:<br />

Recensement de la populati<strong>on</strong>, INSEE, 1999; Germany: Central Register <strong>on</strong> Foreigners, 2002; Greece:<br />

Populati<strong>on</strong> Census, 2001; Hungary: Populati<strong>on</strong> Census, 2001; Iceland: Statistics Iceland, 2003; Iran:<br />

Statistical Centre of Iran, 2003; Ireland: nd; Israel: Central Bureau of Statistics, mid-2003; Italy:<br />

Residence permits 31.08.2004; Japan: Japan Statistics Bureau, 2000; Jordan: Populati<strong>on</strong> and Housing<br />

Census 1994; Latvia: Populati<strong>on</strong> and Housing Census, 2000; Lithuania: Populati<strong>on</strong> and Housing Census<br />

2001; Luxembourg: RP2001; Malta: nd; Morocco: Directi<strong>on</strong> Gén. Sûreté Générale, 2002; Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands:<br />

Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands statistics, 2004; New Zealand: Populati<strong>on</strong> census, 2001; Norway: Statistics Norway, <strong>2005</strong>;<br />

Palestinian Territory: Israel, Central Bureau of Stat, end 2004; Poland: nd; Portugal: 2003; Romania:<br />

Census of Populati<strong>on</strong>, 2002; Slovakia: nd; Slovenia: Populati<strong>on</strong> Census, 2000; South Africa: Statistics<br />

South Africa,2003; Spain: Residence permits 31.12.2003; Sweden: Statistics Sweden, 2003; Switzerland:<br />

Office fédéral de l’immigrati<strong>on</strong>, 2003; Tunisia : Recensement de la Populati<strong>on</strong> 2004; Turkey: Populati<strong>on</strong><br />

Census of 2000; United Kingdom: 2001 Census; United States: 2000, U.S. Census Bureau, Census.


In light of <strong>the</strong> rising oil prices and <strong>the</strong> sec<strong>on</strong>d and first generati<strong>on</strong> migrants<br />

resulting revenues that are expected<br />

to even exceed those of <strong>the</strong> 1970s and<br />

(Fargue, <strong>2005</strong>).<br />

1980s; fiscal balances and external cur- Statistics provided by <strong>the</strong> EU memrent<br />

account balances are greatly improber states report <strong>the</strong> presence of an<br />

ving creating a str<strong>on</strong>g domestic demand. aggregated 5.8 milli<strong>on</strong> migrants of Med-<br />

The regi<strong>on</strong>al current surplus is projected MENA origin. Two traditi<strong>on</strong>al countries<br />

to reach 23.5% of GDP in 2006 (IMF, of destinati<strong>on</strong>, Germany and France,<br />

<strong>2005</strong>).<br />

toge<strong>the</strong>r host almost three-quarters<br />

of this number, <strong>the</strong> remaining quar-<br />

This cash gift is an opportunity for <strong>the</strong> ter being distributed am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

oil-surplus GCC countries to accelerate twenty-three EU member states (Figure<br />

reforms that would generate employ- 15). Am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> three countries ranking<br />

ment for <strong>the</strong> rapidly growing working age next—<strong>the</strong> Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands, Spain and Italy—<br />

populati<strong>on</strong> as well as increase demand <strong>the</strong> last two act as a new magnet for<br />

for foreign labor.<br />

South-Mediterranean migrant workers.<br />

The main countries of origin are: <strong>the</strong><br />

The flow towards Europe<br />

Between 5.0 and 6.4 milli<strong>on</strong> Med-MENA<br />

Palestinian Territories, Turkey, Morocco<br />

and Egypt.<br />

first-generati<strong>on</strong> migrants reside in Europe Figure 16 indicates <strong>the</strong> existence of<br />

(unrecorded migrants not included). This specific patterns of destinati<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g<br />

number does not include ‘sec<strong>on</strong>d-gene- different countries of origin. Migrants<br />

rati<strong>on</strong>’ migrants. In general it is esti- from <strong>the</strong> Maghreb and Turkey are premated<br />

that <strong>the</strong>re are about 10.6 milli<strong>on</strong> dominantly destined for Europe, while<br />

Figure 16: Distributi<strong>on</strong> of Migrants originating from 7 Med Countries by Regi<strong>on</strong> of<br />

Destinati<strong>on</strong> According to origin countries data<br />

Notes: Israel, Jordan and Syria do not provide statistics of <strong>the</strong>ir nati<strong>on</strong>als abroad by country of residence<br />

and are not included<br />

Source: Fargue, <strong>2005</strong>, based <strong>on</strong> calculati<strong>on</strong>s from:<br />

1/ C<strong>on</strong>seil Nati<strong>on</strong>al Éc<strong>on</strong>omique et Social (1997), Commissi<strong>on</strong> de la Communauté Algérienne à l’Étranger<br />

«Situati<strong>on</strong> de la communauté algérienne à l’étranger» étude préliminaire; 2/ CAPMAS (2001); 3/ Choghig<br />

Kasparian, L’entrée des jeunes libanais dans la vie active et l émigrati<strong>on</strong> depuis 1975, Université Saint<br />

Joseph de Beyrouth, 2003; 4/ Ministère des Affaires étrangères et de la Coopérati<strong>on</strong>, Maroc, 2004;<br />

5/ Palestinian Central Bureau of Statistics, Statistical Abstract of Palestine, No4. Ramallah, 2003;<br />

6/ Ministère des Affaires Etrangères, Tunis, <strong>2005</strong>; 7/ General Directorate of Services for <strong>the</strong> Workers<br />

Abroad, Attached to <strong>the</strong> Ministry of Labour and Social Security (2002).<br />

-83-


those from Eastern Arab Mediterranean<br />

countries are instead destined for <strong>the</strong><br />

GCC countries and o<strong>the</strong>r regi<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>the</strong><br />

world.<br />

Remittances play a central role in <strong>the</strong><br />

m<strong>on</strong>etary stability of many developing<br />

countries and are crucial to <strong>the</strong> survival<br />

of poor households. For <strong>the</strong>se last two<br />

decades or more, migrants’ remittances<br />

to North Africa have c<strong>on</strong>stituted <strong>the</strong><br />

highest ratio to GDP of any regi<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong><br />

world: in 2002, <strong>the</strong>y were 3,1% of GDP,<br />

compared with 1,6% for Latin America<br />

and 0,6% for sub-Saharan Africa – <strong>the</strong><br />

latter, <strong>the</strong> lowest ratio in <strong>the</strong> world<br />

(Gallina, 2004).<br />

Since Barcel<strong>on</strong>a Declarati<strong>on</strong>, and <strong>the</strong><br />

launch of <strong>the</strong> <strong>partnership</strong> agreement, <strong>the</strong><br />

flows of remittances became an important<br />

source of income to <strong>the</strong> MPs (Table<br />

X20), as it represents over 35 percent<br />

of <strong>the</strong> value of exports in Morocco and<br />

Egypt, and more than 50 percent of <strong>the</strong><br />

value of exports for Jordan.<br />

It appears that remittances are more<br />

important to <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong> than aid flows.<br />

As development aid from <strong>the</strong> EU -<br />

under <strong>the</strong> MEDA program launched with<br />

<strong>the</strong> Barcel<strong>on</strong>a Process- in 8 of <strong>the</strong> 12<br />

Mediterranean countries is less than 1<br />

billi<strong>on</strong> USD per year, in additi<strong>on</strong> to ano<strong>the</strong>r<br />

billi<strong>on</strong> as loans from <strong>the</strong> European<br />

Bank of Investments. This aid, about 9<br />

Table X20: Worker’s Remittances inflows (billi<strong>on</strong> $)<br />

-84-<br />

USD per capita, is expected to provide<br />

a boot to <strong>the</strong> modernizati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omies<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Mediterranean,<br />

and encouraging <strong>the</strong>m to compete in<br />

a completely free market with <strong>the</strong> EU<br />

partners by 2010. Remittances instead<br />

are not <strong>on</strong>ly larger and more stable, but<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tribute directly to <strong>the</strong> welfare of low<br />

income households located in both rural<br />

and urban areas (Gallina, 2004).<br />

The challenge of integrati<strong>on</strong>: <strong>the</strong><br />

case of Turkish migrati<strong>on</strong> to <strong>the</strong> EU<br />

One of <strong>the</strong> major debates that accompany<br />

<strong>the</strong> Turkish membership to <strong>the</strong> EU is<br />

its effect <strong>on</strong> labour migrati<strong>on</strong>. Between<br />

<strong>the</strong> opp<strong>on</strong>ent’s view that this could open<br />

<strong>the</strong> door to an unrestricted migrati<strong>on</strong><br />

coming from a country with 72 milli<strong>on</strong><br />

people, and <strong>the</strong> supporter’s view that<br />

sees that <strong>the</strong> young labour force migrating<br />

from Turkey can offset <strong>the</strong> effects of<br />

<strong>the</strong> rapidly ageing populati<strong>on</strong> in Europe,<br />

<strong>the</strong> complexity of <strong>the</strong> issue remains and<br />

<strong>the</strong> negotiati<strong>on</strong>s with <strong>the</strong> EU still stand<br />

a l<strong>on</strong>g way.<br />

The official number of Turkish migrants<br />

in <strong>the</strong> EU is hard to find, <strong>the</strong> rough figure<br />

estimates <strong>the</strong>m at around 4 milli<strong>on</strong><br />

between migrants and refugees. 93% of<br />

those are c<strong>on</strong>centrated in <strong>on</strong>ly four EU<br />

countries: Germany al<strong>on</strong>e hosts about<br />

70% of <strong>the</strong> Turks migrants; <strong>the</strong> remaining<br />

share is distributed between <strong>the</strong><br />

1996<br />

2004**<br />

2000 2004* % of GDP % of exports<br />

Egypt 3,1 2,9 3,0 4,0 39,0<br />

Jordan 1,7 1,8 2,2 19,7 56,4<br />

Morocco 2,2 2,2 3,6 7,2 37,1<br />

Turkey 3,5 4,6 0,7 0,2 1,1<br />

Source: Global Development Finance <strong>2005</strong>: Mobilizing Finance and Managing Vulnerability<br />

**Calculati<strong>on</strong>s from World Development report 2006 and Global Development Finance <strong>2005</strong>


Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands (9%), France (8.7%), and<br />

Austria (4.4%). More than half of those<br />

migrants have joined those countries’<br />

labour force and have c<strong>on</strong>tributed with a<br />

share of 0.7% of <strong>the</strong>se countries’ GDP.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong> to <strong>the</strong>ir large number in<br />

Europe, Turks c<strong>on</strong>stitute an ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

power that is still underestimated <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>al and internati<strong>on</strong>al levels.<br />

According to a Turkish Research center,<br />

<strong>the</strong> amount of Turkish investment in <strong>the</strong><br />

EU has increased by more than 50% in<br />

<strong>the</strong> past 7 years with a growing number<br />

of Turkish entrepreneurs (more than<br />

6% of Turkish work force are entrepreneurs).<br />

The number of Turkish migrants to<br />

Germany is <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> rise. The OECD estimates<br />

<strong>the</strong> Turkish citizens to be about<br />

1.9 milli<strong>on</strong> (where 46% of those are<br />

women). More than 832,000 Turkish<br />

are working in this country (70% of<br />

Turkish migrants labour force is located<br />

in Germany) and c<strong>on</strong>tributing 2% to<br />

<strong>the</strong> country’s total GDP. However <strong>the</strong><br />

Turkish residents are still facing difficulties<br />

integrating into <strong>the</strong> German society.<br />

Provoked by <strong>the</strong> former policy to treat<br />

Turks as ‘guests’, <strong>the</strong>y have been isolated<br />

(especially women that bel<strong>on</strong>g to <strong>the</strong><br />

most disadvantage group). Most of <strong>the</strong>m<br />

-85-<br />

do not carry German passports and<br />

some do not even speak <strong>the</strong> language.<br />

The policy of rejecting integrati<strong>on</strong> was<br />

an impulse to <strong>the</strong> formati<strong>on</strong> and development<br />

of fundamentalist groups within<br />

<strong>the</strong> Turkish community.<br />

A new Immigrati<strong>on</strong> law was introduced<br />

in January <strong>2005</strong> that calls to streamline<br />

immigrati<strong>on</strong> procedures, improve <strong>the</strong><br />

integrati<strong>on</strong> of immigrants and ease entry<br />

for skilled workers in certain sectors.<br />

Despite <strong>the</strong> fact that this law is c<strong>on</strong>sidered<br />

a first step to integrate <strong>the</strong> Turks<br />

into <strong>the</strong> German society, it fails to abolish<br />

<strong>the</strong> temporary status of thousands<br />

of refugees, and doesn’t fully address<br />

integrati<strong>on</strong> and naturalizati<strong>on</strong> issues.<br />

Some suggests that <strong>the</strong>re is a need to<br />

first integrate <strong>the</strong> existent residents<br />

into <strong>the</strong> society before admitting more<br />

migrants to avoid <strong>the</strong> risk of creating<br />

parallel societies.<br />

The EU, and specially Germany, main<br />

fears are that by formalizing migrati<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong>re is a risk of increasing <strong>the</strong> already<br />

existent unemployment problem in some<br />

European countries and that <strong>the</strong> type of<br />

skills of migrants does not match <strong>the</strong><br />

need of <strong>the</strong>ir labor force. This justifies<br />

<strong>the</strong> high rates of unemployment (way<br />

above <strong>the</strong> countries’ averages) am<strong>on</strong>g<br />

Table X21: Participati<strong>on</strong> rate *in selected OECD countries. 2002-2003 average<br />

Austria Belgium Switzerland Germany Denmark France Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands Sweden UK<br />

Global rate 71,7 64,2 81,2 71,8 79,7 69,2 76,4 78,0 75,3<br />

of which<br />

Foreigners<br />

74,1 57,0 80,2 65,0 64,2 62,5 61,3 66,0 67,0<br />

of which Turkish 64,7 39,8 74,9 58,9 46,9 55,8 57,6 47,4 51,3<br />

Women 41,6 22,3 61,7 40,4 - 30,4 45,1 - 24,8<br />

Men 83,5 60,5 83,4 74,8 51,6 78,6 69,7 70,8 76,9<br />

Note: The sign “-” indicates that <strong>the</strong> estimate is not statistically significant.<br />

*The participati<strong>on</strong> rate refers to pers<strong>on</strong> aged 15 to 64 years who are in <strong>the</strong> labour force divided by <strong>the</strong><br />

working age populati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Source: OECD calculati<strong>on</strong> based <strong>on</strong> The European Commissi<strong>on</strong> labour survey, <strong>2005</strong>


Turkish migrants in some EU coun-<br />

tries, especially France and Belgium.<br />

On ano<strong>the</strong>r fr<strong>on</strong>t, some European countries<br />

such as Ireland, Spain and <strong>the</strong><br />

United Kingdom are admitting increasing<br />

numbers of immigrant workers because<br />

migrants bring skills unavailable locally<br />

and fill <strong>the</strong> large number of jobs in agriculture,<br />

health, and services that natives<br />

are unwilling or unavailable to take.<br />

On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, some suggests that a<br />

slowdown (or suspensi<strong>on</strong>) in <strong>the</strong> Turkey’s<br />

accessi<strong>on</strong> process may have a substantial<br />

negative impact <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> migrati<strong>on</strong><br />

issue. From an ec<strong>on</strong>omic point of view,<br />

slowing <strong>the</strong> process leads to low growth<br />

and increase in unemployment in Turkey.<br />

This might also slow or suspend <strong>the</strong> political<br />

and ec<strong>on</strong>omic reform that has been<br />

<strong>on</strong>going in Turkey. This would increase<br />

<strong>the</strong> general feeling of insecurity and<br />

hence <strong>the</strong> number of potential migrants<br />

(legal or illegal) will increase.<br />

Under <strong>the</strong> currently strict regimes, net<br />

migrati<strong>on</strong> from Turkey to <strong>the</strong> EU accounts<br />

for a minimum of 35,000 pers<strong>on</strong>s a year.<br />

It is expected that <strong>the</strong>se trends will<br />

accelerate in <strong>the</strong> future if no regulati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

are set to formalize migrati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

In a study to estimate <strong>the</strong> eventual<br />

immigrati<strong>on</strong> from Turkey to <strong>the</strong> EU when<br />

-86-<br />

Turkey becomes a full member, scenarios<br />

are withdrawn for <strong>the</strong> period 2004<br />

to 2030 based <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> experiences of<br />

various groups. These scenarios estimated<br />

a net migrati<strong>on</strong> from Turkey to EU-15<br />

until 2030 between 0.5 and 4.4 milli<strong>on</strong>,<br />

assuming free mobility of labor in about<br />

10 years from now (figures that are way<br />

less than those estimated in case membership<br />

in <strong>the</strong> EU is suspended)<br />

Opening up of Turkey and its possible<br />

accessi<strong>on</strong> to <strong>the</strong> EU represents a<br />

big challenge; however <strong>the</strong> undergoing<br />

development and <strong>the</strong> increasing integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

of Turkey into <strong>the</strong> world ec<strong>on</strong>omy<br />

will diminish <strong>the</strong> role of migrati<strong>on</strong>. In<br />

<strong>the</strong> past few years, <strong>the</strong> Turkish government<br />

has started to take serious steps<br />

towards formulating and implementing<br />

<strong>the</strong> necessary EU migrati<strong>on</strong> policies.<br />

However it is clear that <strong>the</strong> quicker <strong>the</strong><br />

debate begins, <strong>the</strong> more <strong>the</strong> political and<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic expectati<strong>on</strong>s focusing <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

growth of <strong>the</strong> Turkish ec<strong>on</strong>omy will reinforce<br />

this tendency. The future challenge<br />

would be <strong>on</strong> how to integrate <strong>the</strong> Turkish<br />

immigrants already in Europe ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

than focusing <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> new migrants to<br />

<strong>the</strong> EU. It is even expected that some<br />

Turkish migrants would be willing to<br />

return back to <strong>the</strong>ir home country after<br />

<strong>the</strong> integrati<strong>on</strong> (following <strong>the</strong> examples<br />

of Greece, Spain and Portugal).<br />

Table X22: Unemployment rate* in selected OECD countries. 2002-2003 average<br />

Austria Belgium Switzerland Germany Denmark France Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands Sweden UK<br />

Global rate<br />

of which<br />

4,8 7,3 3,6 9,2 4,9 8,9 3,1 5,3 5,0<br />

Foreigners<br />

of which<br />

9,0 17,5 7,3 15,1 12,9 18,5 7,4 12,4 8,0<br />

Turkish<br />

foreigners<br />

13,7 34,2 12,6 19,1 - 25,4 - - -<br />

Women 13,0 48,1 14,9 17,9 - 38,4 - - -<br />

Men 13,9 28,3 11,6 19,7 - 20,8 - - -<br />

Note: The sign “-” indicates that <strong>the</strong> estimate is not statistically significant.<br />

* The unemployment rate refers to pers<strong>on</strong>s aged 15 to 64 years who are in unemployed divided by <strong>the</strong><br />

labour force.<br />

Source: OECD calculati<strong>on</strong> based <strong>on</strong> The European Commissi<strong>on</strong> labour survey, <strong>2005</strong>


Towards a Fair Euro Mediterranean<br />

Migrati<strong>on</strong> approach: Challenges and<br />

Opportunities<br />

In <strong>the</strong> Barcel<strong>on</strong>a Summit of November<br />

<strong>2005</strong>, although <strong>the</strong> Summit chairman’s<br />

statement called for <strong>the</strong> “creati<strong>on</strong> an<br />

area of mutual cooperati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> migrati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

social integrati<strong>on</strong>, justice, and security<br />

and streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>the</strong> management of<br />

regular migratory flows in a comprehensive<br />

manner beneficial to <strong>the</strong> peoples<br />

of both shores of <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean”.<br />

It appears that <strong>the</strong> negotiati<strong>on</strong>s in<br />

this field tend to focus mainly <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

European c<strong>on</strong>cerns regarding <strong>the</strong> subject<br />

of migrati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

During negotiati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>the</strong> heads of states<br />

of <strong>the</strong> EU have put c<strong>on</strong>siderable emphasis<br />

<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> issues of combating illegal<br />

migrati<strong>on</strong>, regulating migrati<strong>on</strong> flows<br />

and social cohesi<strong>on</strong>. This is reflected<br />

in <strong>the</strong> Summit’s final declarati<strong>on</strong> which<br />

stipulated that <strong>the</strong> Euro Mediterranean<br />

partners will develop mechanisms for<br />

cooperati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> fight of illegal migrati<strong>on</strong><br />

including readmissi<strong>on</strong> agreements,<br />

combating human trafficking and capacity<br />

building in border management.<br />

In an attempt to draw guiding principles<br />

for a migrati<strong>on</strong> policy, <strong>the</strong> Barcel<strong>on</strong>a<br />

Summit’s Five Year Work Programme<br />

acknowledged that “Migrati<strong>on</strong>, Social<br />

Integrati<strong>on</strong>, Justice and Security are<br />

issues of comm<strong>on</strong> interest in <strong>the</strong><br />

Partnership, and should be addressed<br />

through a comprehensive and integrated<br />

approach”, and that <strong>the</strong> Euro-<br />

Mediterranean <strong>partnership</strong> will enhance<br />

co-operati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong>se fields to:<br />

√ Promote legal migrati<strong>on</strong> opportunities,<br />

work towards <strong>the</strong> facilitati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

-87-<br />

<strong>the</strong> legal movement of individuals,<br />

recognizing that <strong>the</strong>se c<strong>on</strong>stitute an<br />

opportunity for ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth and<br />

a mean of improving links between<br />

countries, fair treatment and integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

policies for legal migrants, and<br />

facilitate <strong>the</strong> flow of remittance transfers<br />

and address ‘brain drain’;<br />

√ Reduce significantly <strong>the</strong> level of illegal<br />

migrati<strong>on</strong>, trafficking in human beings<br />

and loss of life through hazardous sea<br />

and border crossings;<br />

√ C<strong>on</strong>tinue to pursue <strong>the</strong> modernizati<strong>on</strong><br />

and efficiency of <strong>the</strong> administrati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

justice and facilitate access to justice<br />

by citizens;<br />

√ Reinforce judicial co-operati<strong>on</strong>, including<br />

<strong>on</strong> cross border issues.<br />

In order to be able to reach a fair migrati<strong>on</strong><br />

policy, certain challenges need to be<br />

addressed. The new policy must answer<br />

<strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerns of <strong>the</strong> EU regarding how to<br />

deal with combating illegal migrants (<strong>on</strong><br />

bilateral basis and under <strong>the</strong> European<br />

Neighborhood Policy), social cohesi<strong>on</strong><br />

and integrati<strong>on</strong> of sec<strong>on</strong>d generati<strong>on</strong><br />

migrants. But also, it has to take into<br />

c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> windows of opportunity<br />

for <strong>the</strong> MPs represented in demographic<br />

gap in <strong>the</strong> EU, and <strong>the</strong> agreement<br />

and mode 4 of supply of services under<br />

GATS.<br />

√ Firstly, it is noticed that “clandestine”<br />

migrati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean<br />

regi<strong>on</strong> has increased dramatically in <strong>the</strong><br />

last decade, although European regulati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

and cross-border rules have been<br />

streng<strong>the</strong>ned. Also, ano<strong>the</strong>r new phenomen<strong>on</strong><br />

which appears in <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong><br />

is <strong>the</strong> transit migrati<strong>on</strong>, as most of <strong>the</strong>


Maghreb countries have turned into<br />

transit countries for migrants from Sub-<br />

Saharan Africa and Middle East to pass<br />

to European countries. Estimates show<br />

that annually about 100,000 to 120,000<br />

cross <strong>the</strong> Mediterranean illegally, am<strong>on</strong>g<br />

those about 35,000 are from sub Saharan<br />

Africa (Baldwin, <strong>2005</strong>). In 2003 9800<br />

illegal migrant have been caught in<br />

Morocco al<strong>on</strong>e, am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m 6600 were<br />

from sub Saharan Africa.<br />

The EU is intent <strong>on</strong> using <strong>the</strong> European<br />

Neighborhood and Partnership<br />

Instruments to intensify its cooperati<strong>on</strong><br />

with Mediterranean third countries <strong>on</strong><br />

migrati<strong>on</strong> management. This cooperati<strong>on</strong><br />

will be country-specific or “differentiated”,<br />

in <strong>the</strong> European-Neighborhood-<br />

Policy manner of speaking.<br />

√ Sec<strong>on</strong>dly, <strong>the</strong>re is a very str<strong>on</strong>g<br />

need for comprehensive migrants’ integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

policies. Primarily, migrati<strong>on</strong><br />

policies have been primarily defensive<br />

and c<strong>on</strong>trol-centered instead of proactive.<br />

Similarly, integrati<strong>on</strong> policies for<br />

immigrants have been reactive. In many<br />

cases, poor integrati<strong>on</strong> policy has c<strong>on</strong>tributed<br />

to negative percepti<strong>on</strong>s of immigrants,<br />

which in turn has led to <strong>the</strong><br />

reinforcement of defensive immigrati<strong>on</strong><br />

policies.<br />

Here, numerous n<strong>on</strong>-governmental actors<br />

can str<strong>on</strong>gly influence <strong>the</strong> migrant’s integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

process. These vital instituti<strong>on</strong>al<br />

actors include churches, trade uni<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

employers’ organizati<strong>on</strong>s, political parties,<br />

<strong>the</strong> media, and o<strong>the</strong>r civil society<br />

actors. Government policies that aim<br />

at steering processes of settlement and<br />

integrati<strong>on</strong> should actively involve not<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly immigrants <strong>the</strong>mselves, but also<br />

those important players in civil society.<br />

-88-<br />

Such n<strong>on</strong>-governmental partners are<br />

important in two ways. First and foremost,<br />

<strong>the</strong>y functi<strong>on</strong> as direct partners<br />

in <strong>the</strong> implementati<strong>on</strong> of policies. But<br />

<strong>the</strong>y are perhaps even more important<br />

as political actors. They may influence<br />

<strong>the</strong> political climate and political outcomes,<br />

and may be important agents in<br />

combating exclusi<strong>on</strong>, discriminati<strong>on</strong>, and<br />

xenophobia. (Penninx, 2004).<br />

√ On ano<strong>the</strong>r fr<strong>on</strong>t, as highlighted<br />

before by FEMISE, <strong>the</strong> MPs can benefit<br />

from <strong>the</strong> window of opportunity which<br />

<strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>trast of demographic structures<br />

of European countries compared to MPs<br />

offer. For while Europe is ageing rapidly,<br />

<strong>the</strong> MPs enjoy populati<strong>on</strong> predominant<br />

by youth. If <strong>the</strong> labor force participati<strong>on</strong><br />

rates remain c<strong>on</strong>stant in <strong>the</strong> EU, an<br />

ever-increasing share of <strong>the</strong> populati<strong>on</strong><br />

will be inactive as a result of old age<br />

which will negatively affect <strong>the</strong> l<strong>on</strong>g term<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth.<br />

In order to determine <strong>the</strong> potential<br />

immigrati<strong>on</strong> needs of <strong>the</strong> current EU<br />

countries, <strong>the</strong> ILO performed a combined<br />

demographic and ec<strong>on</strong>omic analysis<br />

to assess how ageing would reduce <strong>the</strong><br />

standard of living (as measured by per<br />

capita GDP).<br />

For <strong>the</strong> purpose of <strong>the</strong> exercise <strong>the</strong> GDP<br />

per capita and hence <strong>the</strong> average per<br />

capita c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> level is targeted to<br />

increase in real terms by about 3 percent<br />

per annum. The analysis using a<br />

simulati<strong>on</strong> model predicts a substantial<br />

labor shortage of about 38 milli<strong>on</strong> workers<br />

by 2050, assuming a rise in labor<br />

productivity of 2.5 %. If productivity<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly increases by 2 % a year, <strong>the</strong> shortage<br />

grows to 88 milli<strong>on</strong> workers. The<br />

effect <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> “gap between <strong>the</strong> targe-


ted standard of living and <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>e that<br />

is possible” would be substantial. Per<br />

capita GDP would be <strong>on</strong>ly 78% of <strong>the</strong><br />

expected level by 2050 (ILO, 2004b).<br />

√ Ano<strong>the</strong>r opportunity that needs<br />

to be exploited by <strong>the</strong> MPs is <strong>the</strong> supply<br />

of services by a natural pers<strong>on</strong> under<br />

GATS mode 4. However, even by <strong>the</strong><br />

modest standards of services liberalizati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

little was d<strong>on</strong>e <strong>on</strong> liberalizing<br />

<strong>the</strong> temporary movement of service<br />

suppliers and most countries made <strong>on</strong>ly<br />

limited commitments <strong>on</strong> mode 4. The EU<br />

tends to strict <strong>the</strong> Mode 4 liberalizati<strong>on</strong><br />

to highly qualified workers <strong>on</strong>ly, as well<br />

as planning <strong>the</strong> management of Mode 4<br />

immigrati<strong>on</strong> by Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Needs Tests or<br />

quotas to avoid labor market shocks.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> short term, <strong>the</strong> MPs need to<br />

analyze more thoroughly <strong>the</strong> full implicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

of GATS Mode 4 and how <strong>the</strong>y<br />

can benefit from it by orienting <strong>the</strong><br />

negotiati<strong>on</strong> towards <strong>the</strong> deepening of<br />

liberalizati<strong>on</strong> in this area in a way that<br />

gives <strong>the</strong> MPs access to <strong>the</strong> European<br />

labor market.<br />

Hence, <strong>the</strong> new migrati<strong>on</strong> policy needs<br />

to be designed in such a way as to<br />

promote and encourage regulated n<strong>on</strong>permanent<br />

flows. This form of migrati<strong>on</strong><br />

is dynamic, more equitable and insures<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tinuous flows. Moreover, this n<strong>on</strong>permanent<br />

migrati<strong>on</strong> will ensure <strong>the</strong><br />

fulfillment of <strong>the</strong> labor requirements of<br />

<strong>the</strong> European countries without causing<br />

social problems. In additi<strong>on</strong>, if migrati<strong>on</strong><br />

is c<strong>on</strong>ceived <strong>on</strong> a temporary basis, it can<br />

be designed in such a way as to enhance<br />

migrants’ skills thanks to <strong>the</strong> professi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

experience <strong>the</strong>y acquire abroad;<br />

migrati<strong>on</strong> could thus become part of a<br />

strategy for enhancing human capital in<br />

-89-<br />

countries of origin; in o<strong>the</strong>r words, turning<br />

“brain drain” to “brain gain”.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> :<br />

The cross-border movement of people<br />

is a substantial and widespread<br />

phe¬nomen<strong>on</strong> involving more than 10<br />

milli<strong>on</strong> people a year over <strong>the</strong> past<br />

decade, as well as a growing number<br />

of countries (ILO, 2004c). However, a<br />

major gap in <strong>the</strong> current instituti<strong>on</strong>al<br />

structure is <strong>the</strong> absence of a multilateral<br />

framework for governing this matter.<br />

From <strong>the</strong> World Commissi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Social<br />

Dimensi<strong>on</strong> of Globalizati<strong>on</strong>’s perspective,<br />

<strong>the</strong> lack of a multilateral framework<br />

<strong>on</strong> migrati<strong>on</strong> is a clear illustrati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong> imbalance in <strong>the</strong> current rules of<br />

<strong>the</strong> game. While <strong>the</strong> rights of foreign<br />

investment have been in¬creasingly<br />

streng<strong>the</strong>ned in <strong>the</strong> rules set for <strong>the</strong><br />

global ec<strong>on</strong>omy, those of migrant workers<br />

have received far less attenti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Thus, a multilateral regime for <strong>the</strong> crossborder<br />

movement of people that makes<br />

<strong>the</strong> process more orderly and eliminates<br />

<strong>the</strong> exploitati<strong>on</strong> of migrants could offer<br />

c<strong>on</strong>siderable gains to all.<br />

Through <strong>the</strong> protracted process of services<br />

negotiati<strong>on</strong>s in <strong>the</strong> WTO (Doha,<br />

Cancun, H<strong>on</strong>g K<strong>on</strong>g), <strong>the</strong> GATS «Mode<br />

4» provisi<strong>on</strong>s remain weak, very limited<br />

and restricted to <strong>the</strong> temporary movement<br />

of service providers and so covers<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly a tiny fracti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> cross-border<br />

movement of labor.<br />

Much can be d<strong>on</strong>e to improve significantly<br />

up<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> current situati<strong>on</strong>. The issue<br />

of developing a multilateral framework<br />

to govern internati<strong>on</strong>al migrati<strong>on</strong> should<br />

now be placed firmly <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> internati<strong>on</strong>al


agenda. The objectives of such a fra-<br />

mework should be (ILO, 2004c):<br />

√ To facilitate mutually beneficial ways<br />

of increasing migrati<strong>on</strong> opportunities<br />

and ensure that <strong>the</strong> process is fair to<br />

both sending and receiving countries;<br />

√ To make <strong>the</strong> process orderly, predictable<br />

and legal;<br />

-90-<br />

√ To eliminate trafficking and o<strong>the</strong>r current<br />

abuses where women are especially<br />

vulnerable;<br />

√ To ensure full protecti<strong>on</strong> for <strong>the</strong> rights<br />

of migrant workers and facilitate <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

local integrati<strong>on</strong>;<br />

√ To maximize <strong>the</strong> developmental benefits<br />

of internati<strong>on</strong>al migrati<strong>on</strong>.


Notes<br />

[1]: Informality is referred to enterprises<br />

that do not respect legal<br />

procedures for <strong>the</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> and<br />

exploitati<strong>on</strong> of society, namely<br />

registrati<strong>on</strong>, license, social security,<br />

taxati<strong>on</strong>, etc... Data established<br />

by Egyptian Labour Market<br />

survey (ELMS), 1998.<br />

[2]: Source: Egyptian Labour Market<br />

survey (ELMS), 1998.<br />

[3]: Formality is defined by three<br />

major characteristics: (i) being<br />

registered; (ii) possessing a<br />

[4]:<br />

license and (iii) holding recurrent<br />

accountancy.<br />

The index is calculated as such:<br />

4 1 ⎛ f<br />

⎞<br />

ai − fbi<br />

Index1=<br />

∑ ⎜ × 100 ⎟<br />

4 i= 1 ⎝ fbi<br />

⎠<br />

where fai = value of factor i <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> date of survey and fbi = value<br />

of factor i a year later.<br />

[5]: This index was calculated according<br />

to values of each of <strong>the</strong>se<br />

variables with: value (1) given to<br />

each expected growing variable.<br />

(0) for variables that should be stable<br />

and (-1) for those that should<br />

decrease. The score for each enterprise<br />

is standardized to bel<strong>on</strong>g to<br />

<strong>the</strong> interval [-100%; 100%].<br />

[6]: It should be noted that Egypt<br />

witnessed a recessi<strong>on</strong> in 2003<br />

and 2004, which affected <strong>the</strong> percepti<strong>on</strong><br />

of enterprises.<br />

[7]: Study FEM22-22, c<strong>on</strong>ducted by<br />

CEFI.<br />

[8]: An enterprise here is c<strong>on</strong>sidered<br />

as <strong>on</strong>e turning towards export if<br />

at least 10% of its turnover is<br />

destined to <strong>the</strong> external market.<br />

[9]: Analysis according to data collected<br />

<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> occasi<strong>on</strong> of annual<br />

surveys with public and private<br />

enterprises with more than 10<br />

workers by <strong>the</strong> Turkish nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

statistics institute (level of sectors<br />

with four figure internati<strong>on</strong>al classificati<strong>on</strong><br />

of industrial types).<br />

[10]: Cf. FEM22-22, Cefi op. cit.. Firms<br />

that entered or exited during <strong>the</strong><br />

period are obliterated.<br />

[11]: Ei<strong>the</strong>r imports/ (imports + producti<strong>on</strong><br />

or turnover).<br />

-91-<br />

[12]: Study FEM22-20 c<strong>on</strong>ducted by<br />

ROSES.<br />

[13]: Cf. Marc Lautier, Care and Cepii,<br />

study FEM22-34, c<strong>on</strong>ducted by<br />

Cepii. This secti<strong>on</strong> utilizes in certain<br />

parts a summarized c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong><br />

from <strong>Femise</strong> study written by<br />

Marc Lautier.<br />

[14]: FEM22-22, Cefi, op. cit.<br />

[15]: Flexibility of employment growth<br />

to real industrial added value.<br />

Also, for Morocco, an increase<br />

of 1 point of industrial added<br />

value created 1.13 employment<br />

between 1995 and 2001.<br />

[16]: FEM22-34, Cepii, op. cit.<br />

[17]: FEM22-22, Cefi, op. cit.<br />

[18]: Commissi<strong>on</strong> of European<br />

Communities. European<br />

Commissi<strong>on</strong> (2003). Ec<strong>on</strong>omic and<br />

Competitiveness of <strong>the</strong> European<br />

Textile and Clothing sector in support<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>: <strong>the</strong> Future<br />

of <strong>the</strong> textiles and Clothing sector<br />

in an enlarged Europe. Commissi<strong>on</strong><br />

Staff Working Paper, SEC(2003)<br />

1345, Brussels, Belgium:3-4.<br />

[19]: 99 am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> first 500 industrial<br />

enterprises in Turkey, 16 am<strong>on</strong>g<br />

<strong>the</strong> first 50 of all mixed sectors in<br />

Morocco, 7 am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> first 100 in<br />

Tunisia. Am<strong>on</strong>g 330 largest enterprises<br />

of <strong>the</strong> sector at <strong>the</strong> global<br />

level, 13 are Turkish, 1 Israeli, 2<br />

Egyptian and 1 Syria.<br />

[20]: Figures of Associati<strong>on</strong> Marocain des<br />

Industries du Textile Habillement<br />

(AMITH).<br />

[21]: Nordås, H. K.. The Global Textile<br />

and Clothing Industry post <strong>the</strong><br />

Agreement <strong>on</strong> Textiles and<br />

Clothing.Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper n. 5,<br />

World Trade Organizati<strong>on</strong>, Geneva,<br />

Switzerland, 2004: 16.<br />

[22]: Figures c<strong>on</strong>cerning Tunisia are<br />

much more difficult to find and<br />

are often not published.<br />

[23]: Figures of <strong>the</strong> Haut Commissariat<br />

au Plan, ec<strong>on</strong>omic notes.<br />

[24]: Represents 1690 firms including<br />

997 that registered foreign participati<strong>on</strong><br />

and 623 are totally held<br />

by foreigners.<br />

[25]: This explains <strong>the</strong> advantage of<br />

NPI that succeeded in setting<br />

up <strong>the</strong> network. These countries


have a piercing effect <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> global<br />

clothing market by leaning<br />

<strong>on</strong> wage differential. Success of<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir clothing exports and utilizati<strong>on</strong><br />

of imported fabrics expanded<br />

<strong>the</strong> emergence of local textile<br />

industry. The latter succeeded in<br />

manufacturing fabric in resp<strong>on</strong>se<br />

to demands of local ready-made<br />

garment makers, after being substituted<br />

to imports, <strong>the</strong>se fabrics<br />

were exported. The “setting up of<br />

<strong>the</strong> network” (Cepii, 1978), was<br />

prol<strong>on</strong>ged until <strong>the</strong> syn<strong>the</strong>tic fiber<br />

industry was in turn an exporter.<br />

[26]: Study FEM22-06, c<strong>on</strong>ducted by<br />

Federicco Cafe Center, Roskilde<br />

University<br />

[27]: Study FEM22-02, c<strong>on</strong>ducted by<br />

Bilkent University.<br />

[28]: Complete illustrati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> methodology<br />

and results in FEM22-02<br />

study, Bilkent Univ,. op. cit.<br />

[29] : Study FEM22-36, c<strong>on</strong>ducted by<br />

Catt, EMMA network.<br />

[30]: FEM22-36, Catt, op. cit.<br />

[31]: Estimati<strong>on</strong> obtained from a revolving<br />

model. The cost of transport<br />

is measured according to compilati<strong>on</strong><br />

of three indexes <strong>on</strong> communicati<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

transport by train<br />

and by road.<br />

[32]: According to <strong>the</strong> quality of roads,<br />

existence of deserts separating<br />

MCs are c<strong>on</strong>sidered here, and<br />

development in opening borders<br />

between Morocco and Algeria.<br />

[33]: FEM22-02, Bilkent Univ. op. cit.<br />

[34]: For detailed analysis,, cf. FEM22-<br />

02, Bilkent Univ. op. cit.<br />

[35]: According to FEM22-36, Catt, op. cit.<br />

[36]: Except India.<br />

[37] : They reflect not <strong>on</strong>ly accorded<br />

preferences and degree of integrati<strong>on</strong><br />

of <strong>on</strong>e country with ano<strong>the</strong>r<br />

but equally <strong>the</strong> compositi<strong>on</strong> of<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir exchange flows. For example<br />

<strong>the</strong> case of Uruguay. This country<br />

mainly exports meat and its byproducts.<br />

Preferential c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

were accorded to it by EU but also<br />

to Japan and AELE countries. But<br />

access to <strong>the</strong>se countries’ markets<br />

will not improve for Uruguay<br />

as l<strong>on</strong>g as it imposes high tariffs<br />

<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong>se products.<br />

-92-<br />

[38]: The table is read as follows: globally<br />

Jordan imposes an average<br />

of <strong>the</strong> right of 18.8% <strong>on</strong> products<br />

coming from Algeria.<br />

[39]: The branch is defined as <strong>the</strong><br />

group of fragmented enterprises<br />

manufacturing <strong>the</strong> same product;<br />

<strong>the</strong> sector regroups <strong>the</strong> enterprises<br />

according to <strong>the</strong>ir principal<br />

activity. Intra-branch (interbranches)<br />

exchanges, exchange<br />

products coming from <strong>the</strong> same<br />

industrial branch (from different<br />

industrial branches).<br />

[40]: Results will certainly be more c<strong>on</strong>trasted<br />

if employed tariffs here<br />

were not derived from TRAINS but<br />

from that developed by CEPII.


Bibliography<br />

List of <strong>the</strong> main <strong>Femise</strong> studies used for writing<br />

this report and of <strong>the</strong>ir main c<strong>on</strong>tributors:<br />

FEM22-02: “Impact of Liberalizati<strong>on</strong> of Trade in<br />

Services: Banking, Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

and Maritime Transport in Egypt,<br />

Morocco, Tunisia and Turkey”, c<strong>on</strong>ducted<br />

by Bilkent University, Center for<br />

Internati<strong>on</strong>al Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, coord. Sübidey<br />

Togan in collaborati<strong>on</strong> with Faculty of<br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Political Science, Cairo<br />

University. (Egypt), INSEA (Morocco),<br />

Université de Tunis (Tunisia); December<br />

<strong>2005</strong><br />

C<strong>on</strong>tributors: Driss Abbadi, Erkan Akdemir,<br />

Lahcen Achy, Erdem Basçı, Hakan<br />

Berument, M<strong>on</strong>gi Boughzala, Ahmed<br />

F. Gh<strong>on</strong>eim, Hanaa Kheir-El-Din, Aykut<br />

Kibritçioglu, Dhafer Saidane, Hala Sakr,<br />

Sübidey Togan.<br />

FEM22-06: “The Informal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy Employment<br />

Impacts Of Trade Liberalisati<strong>on</strong> And<br />

Increased Competiti<strong>on</strong> In Export<br />

Markets: The North African Textile,<br />

Clothing And Footwear Sector”, c<strong>on</strong>ducted<br />

by Federico Caffè Centre,<br />

Roskilde Univeristy Denmark, Dir.<br />

Bruno Amoroso, Andrea Gallina, in collaborati<strong>on</strong><br />

with CREAD (Algeria), INSEA<br />

(Morocco), University of Sussex (United<br />

Kingdom), University of Tunis, Tunisia;<br />

October <strong>2005</strong><br />

C<strong>on</strong>tributors: Bruno Amoroso, Bechir Chourou,<br />

Bruno Cozzari, Andrea Gallina, Diana<br />

Hunt, Mehdi Lahlou, Saïb Musette<br />

FEM22-07: “Integrati<strong>on</strong> and enlargement of<br />

<strong>the</strong> European Uni<strong>on</strong>, less<strong>on</strong>s for <strong>the</strong> Arab<br />

regi<strong>on</strong>”, Center for European Studies,<br />

Faculty of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Political<br />

Science, Cairo University, coord. Naglaa<br />

El Ehwany, in collaborati<strong>on</strong> with Faculty<br />

of Law, M<strong>on</strong>ofeya University (Egypt),<br />

University of Jordan, Amman (Jordan),<br />

-93-<br />

University of Essex (United Kingdom),<br />

Migrati<strong>on</strong> Department, ILO and World<br />

Bank, November <strong>2005</strong><br />

C<strong>on</strong>tributors: L<strong>on</strong>ba Abdelatif, Ben Ali Edriss,<br />

Bahaa Ali El Dean, Ibrahim Awad, Heba<br />

El-Laithy, Ahmed F. Gh<strong>on</strong>eim, Amer S.<br />

Jabarin, Hanaa Kheir-El-Din, Alastair<br />

McAuley, Sahar Nasr, Abdallah Shehata<br />

FEM22-20: “Flexibilité du travail et c<strong>on</strong>currence<br />

sur le marché des biens et services :<br />

impact sur les c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s de travail et<br />

le développement du secteur informel<br />

en Algérie, au Maroc et en Tunisie”,<br />

c<strong>on</strong>ducted by le ROSES, université de<br />

Paris I, coord. Gérard Duchêne, Boris<br />

Najman, in collaborati<strong>on</strong> with CREAD<br />

(Algeria), CREQ (Morocco) et ISTIS<br />

(Tunisia); November <strong>2005</strong><br />

C<strong>on</strong>tributors: Fatima Boubekeur, Mohamed<br />

Bougroum, Gérard Duchêne, Alexandra<br />

Froment, Annie Garnero, Nasreddine<br />

Hammouda, Aomar Ibourk, Boris<br />

Najman, Hosni Nemsia<br />

FEM22-22: “Identificati<strong>on</strong> des effets sur la<br />

croissance et l’emploi des mécanismes<br />

d’ajustement micro-éc<strong>on</strong>bomique<br />

de l’offre face à l’ouverture”, c<strong>on</strong>ducted<br />

by CEFI, université de la Méditerranée,<br />

coord. Patricia Augier, Michael Gasiorek,<br />

in collaborati<strong>on</strong> with INSEA (Morocco),<br />

University of Sussex (United Kingdom);<br />

September <strong>2005</strong><br />

C<strong>on</strong>tributors: Lahcen Achy, Patricia Augier,<br />

Amine Basri, Novella Bottini, Mari<strong>on</strong><br />

Dovis, Michael Gasiorek, A. Hassani,<br />

A. Irali, Thomas Lagoarde-Segot, N.<br />

Mounir, Teoman Pamukçu, Charles Lai-<br />

T<strong>on</strong>g, Sandra Palméro, Nathalie Roux<br />

FEM22-34: “Les perspectives de changement<br />

sectoriel dans les pays méditerranéens:<br />

quels secteurs de croissance après l’industrie<br />

légère?”, c<strong>on</strong>ducted by CEPII,<br />

coord. Agnes Chevalier, Jean-Raphael<br />

Chap<strong>on</strong>nière and Marc Lautier, in collaborati<strong>on</strong><br />

with CARE-Université de Rouen


(France), CEPN-Université de Paris 13<br />

(France), ESSEC Tunis (Tunisia), Hebrew<br />

University Jerusalem (Israel), University<br />

of Granada (Spain); July <strong>2005</strong><br />

C<strong>on</strong>tributors: Wifak Barouni, José Camacho,<br />

Jean-Raphael Chap<strong>on</strong>nière, Agnes<br />

Chevalier, Marc Lautier, Juliette Milgram<br />

Baleix, Mercedes Rodriguez Molina,<br />

Alfred Tovias<br />

FEM22-36: “Obstacles to South-South<br />

Integrati<strong>on</strong>, to trade and to foreign<br />

direct investment: <strong>the</strong> MENA countries<br />

case”, c<strong>on</strong>ducted by CATT-Université de<br />

Pau, EMMA network, coord. Jacques Le<br />

Cacheux, in collaborati<strong>on</strong> with University<br />

of Granada; October <strong>2005</strong><br />

C<strong>on</strong>tributors: Antoine Bouët, Jamal Bouoiyour,<br />

Marie-Laure Cheval, Sandy Dall’erba,<br />

Fabrice Darrigues, Sylvain Dejean,<br />

Aomar Ibourk, Saad Isseini, Miren<br />

Lafourcade, Amina Lahrèche-Révil,<br />

Jacques Le Cacheux, Juliette Milgram,<br />

Serge Rey<br />

FEM22-39: “South-South Trade M<strong>on</strong>etary<br />

and Financial Integrati<strong>on</strong> and <strong>the</strong><br />

Euro-Mediterranean Partnership: An<br />

Empirical Investigati<strong>on</strong>”, c<strong>on</strong>ducted<br />

by Institute of Financial Ec<strong>on</strong>omics,<br />

American University of Beirut, Dir.<br />

Sim<strong>on</strong> Neaime; June <strong>2005</strong><br />

C<strong>on</strong>tributors : Rima El-Kadi, Sim<strong>on</strong> Neaime,<br />

Myra Yazbeck<br />

ACHY L. (2002), « Labour market and growth<br />

in Morocco », Global Development<br />

Network.<br />

ADAIR P. (2002), « L’éc<strong>on</strong>omie informelle<br />

au Maghreb : une perspective comparatiste<br />

Algérie-Maroc», C<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> à<br />

la Première Université de Printemps<br />

des Ec<strong>on</strong>omies Méditerranéennes et du<br />

M<strong>on</strong>de Arabe à Tanger, 25-27 avril.<br />

AGENOR P-R. et EL AYNAOUI K. (<strong>2005</strong>),<br />

« Politiques du marché du travail et<br />

chômage au Maroc : une analyse<br />

quantitative », Revue d’Ec<strong>on</strong>omie du<br />

Développement, n°1, mars.<br />

-94-<br />

AIT FARAJI S. et AMOR N. (2004), « Offre<br />

de travail au Maroc : situati<strong>on</strong> et tendance<br />

», dans ETUDES ET METHODES,<br />

Revue de la DPEG, n°1, Ministère des<br />

finances et de la privatisati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Baldwin E. (2004): ‘Mediterranean Migrati<strong>on</strong>s:<br />

Regi<strong>on</strong>alisms versus Globalizati<strong>on</strong>’,<br />

Finisterra, Universidade de Lisboa<br />

Baldwin E. (<strong>2005</strong>), “Migrati<strong>on</strong> In The<br />

Middle East And Mediterranean” A<br />

Regi<strong>on</strong>al Study prepared for <strong>the</strong> Global<br />

Commissi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Migrati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

Mediterranean Migrati<strong>on</strong> Observatory,<br />

University Research Institute for Urban<br />

Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and Human Resources,<br />

Pantei<strong>on</strong> University<br />

BONNAZ H., COURTOT N. et NIVAT D. (1994),<br />

« Le c<strong>on</strong>tenu en emplois des échanges<br />

industriels de la France avec les<br />

pays en développement », Ec<strong>on</strong>omie et<br />

Statistique, n°179-280, pp. 13-34.<br />

BORJAS G. J., FREEMAN R. B. et KATZ L. F.<br />

(1991), « On <strong>the</strong> Labor Market Effects<br />

of Immigrati<strong>on</strong> and Trade », Working<br />

Paper Series, n° 3761, NBER.<br />

BOUSSIDA S. (2004), « Ouverture commerciale<br />

et emploi (cas des industries<br />

manufacturières tunisiennes », IEQ.<br />

BURGESS S., Lane J. et Stevens D. (2000),<br />

« Job Flows, Worker Flows and<br />

Churning », Journal of Labor Ec<strong>on</strong>omics,<br />

18, 473-502.<br />

CABALLERO R. J. et HAMMOUR M. L. (1996),<br />

“On <strong>the</strong> timing and efficiency of creative<br />

destructi<strong>on</strong>,” Quarterly Journal of<br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, 111, 805-852.<br />

CERED (1997), Situati<strong>on</strong> et perspectives<br />

démographiques du Maroc.<br />

CORTE O. et JEAN S. (1995), « Echange<br />

internati<strong>on</strong>al et marché du travail : une<br />

revue critique des méthodes d’analyse<br />

», Revue d’Ec<strong>on</strong>omie Politique, 105, pp.<br />

369-403.<br />

Dasguta D, Nabli MK, Pissarides C et<br />

Varoudakis A (2003), “Making trade<br />

Work for Jobs : Internati<strong>on</strong>al evidence<br />

and less<strong>on</strong>s for MENA” World Bank,<br />

Departemental Working paper 27023,<br />

Juillet 2003.<br />

DAVIS S. J. et HITWANGER J. (1992), « Gross<br />

job creati<strong>on</strong>, gross job destructi<strong>on</strong> and<br />

employment reallocati<strong>on</strong> », Quaterly<br />

Journal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, pp. 819-861.<br />

DAVIS S., HALTIWANGER J. et SCHUH S.<br />

(1996), Job Creati<strong>on</strong> and Destructi<strong>on</strong>,<br />

MIT Press.


DRIVER C., KILPATRICK A. et NAIISBITT B.<br />

(1988), « The sensibility of estimated<br />

employment effect of input studies »,<br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Modeling, pp. 145-150.<br />

EDWARDS (1988), « Terms of trade, tariffs<br />

and labour market adjustment in developing<br />

countries », World Bank Ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

Review, vol 2, pp. 165-85.<br />

Fargue P. (<strong>2005</strong>) Ed., “Mediterranean<br />

Migrati<strong>on</strong> <strong>2005</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Report</str<strong>on</strong>g>”, Cooperati<strong>on</strong><br />

project <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> social integrati<strong>on</strong> of immigrants,<br />

migrati<strong>on</strong>, and <strong>the</strong> movement<br />

of pers<strong>on</strong>s, Financed by <strong>the</strong> European<br />

Commissi<strong>on</strong>, Robert Schumann Center,<br />

European University Institute<br />

Fasano, U and, Rishi G, 2004. “Emerging<br />

Strains in GCC Labor Markets”, paper<br />

in Middle Eastern and North African<br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>omies, electr<strong>on</strong>ic journal, Volume<br />

6, Middle East Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Associati<strong>on</strong> and<br />

Loyola University Chicago, September,<br />

2004. http://www.luc.edu/publicati<strong>on</strong>s/<br />

academic<br />

FEMISE (2003), FEMISE 2003 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Report</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>euro</strong>-Mediterranean <strong>partnership</strong>, http://<br />

www.femise.org<br />

FEMISE (2004), Profil pays Maroc, Institut de<br />

la Méditerranée. http://www.femise.org<br />

FONTAGNE L. et MIRZA D. (2003), « The<br />

Role of Demand in <strong>the</strong> Adjustment of<br />

Employment to Trade”, Paper presented<br />

at <strong>the</strong> GEP c<strong>on</strong>ference <strong>on</strong> Trade<br />

and Labour Perspectives <strong>on</strong> Worker<br />

Turnover, University of Nottingham 27-<br />

28.6.2003.<br />

Gallina A., Amoroso B. (2004), «A favourable<br />

macro-ec<strong>on</strong>omic envir<strong>on</strong>ment, innovative<br />

financial instruments and internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

partner-ship to channel workers’<br />

remittances towards <strong>the</strong> promoti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

local development. Two case studies<br />

in Morocco and Tunisia», étude femise<br />

FEM21-08, http://www.femise.org<br />

Gallina A. (2004), “Migrati<strong>on</strong>, financial<br />

flows and development in <strong>the</strong> Euro-<br />

Mediterranean area”, Research <str<strong>on</strong>g>Report</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

n.5 /2004, Federico Caffè Centre -<br />

Department of Social Sciences, Roskilde<br />

University<br />

GCC, Statistical Bulletin Volume-Twelve,<br />

2003; Gulf Cooperati<strong>on</strong> Council, http:<br />

//www.gcc-sg.org/gccstatvo112/genstat/g4.htm<br />

Girgis, M. (2002) “Nati<strong>on</strong>al Versus Migrant<br />

Workers in <strong>the</strong> GCC” in H. Handoussa<br />

and Z. Tzannatos (eds.), Employment<br />

-95-<br />

Creati<strong>on</strong> and Social Protecti<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong><br />

Middle East and North Africa. Cairo:<br />

AUC Press.<br />

Global Development Finance <strong>2005</strong>: Mobilizing<br />

Finance and Managing Vulnerability, The<br />

World Bank, Washingt<strong>on</strong> DC<br />

HAOUAS I., YAGOUBI M. et HESHMATI A.<br />

(2003), « The impacts of trade liberalizati<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>on</strong> employment and wages in<br />

Tunisian Industries », Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper<br />

n°688.<br />

ILO (2002), Yearbook of Labor Statistics 2002,<br />

The Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labor Organizati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

Geneva<br />

ILO (2004a), Global Employment Trends 2004,<br />

The Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labor Organizati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

Geneva<br />

ILO (2004b), “Towards a Fair Deal For<br />

Migrant Workers in <strong>the</strong> Global Ec<strong>on</strong>omy”,<br />

Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labor C<strong>on</strong>ference, 92nd<br />

Sessi<strong>on</strong>, 2004, The Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labor<br />

Organizati<strong>on</strong>, Geneva<br />

ILO (2004c), “A Fair Globalizati<strong>on</strong>: Creating<br />

Opportunities For all”, Global Commissi<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>on</strong> The Social Dimensi<strong>on</strong> of Globalizati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

The Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labor Organizati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

Geneva<br />

Johns<strong>on</strong> S., Kaufmann D. et P. Zoido-Lobat<strong>on</strong>,<br />

(1998), « Corrupti<strong>on</strong>, Public Finances<br />

and <strong>the</strong> Unofficial Ec<strong>on</strong>omy », World<br />

Bank Policy Research Working Paper no.<br />

2169<br />

LALL S. (2002), “The employment impact of<br />

globalisati<strong>on</strong> in developing countries”,<br />

QEH Working Paper Series, n°93.<br />

MALIRANTA M. (2003), “Micro level dynamics<br />

of productivity growth: An empirical<br />

analysis of <strong>the</strong> great leap in Finnish<br />

manufacturing productivity in 1975-<br />

2000,” Helsinki School of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics,<br />

Doctoral Dissertati<strong>on</strong>s N° A-227.<br />

Menegaldo F, Palméro S et Roux N (2004),<br />

Tendances de la spécialisati<strong>on</strong> des pays<br />

méditerranéens et impact sur la croissance<br />

dans le cadre d’une comparais<strong>on</strong><br />

Partenaires Méditerranéens- Pays de l’Est<br />

Européen, dans « Les effets des accords<br />

d’associati<strong>on</strong> sur l’industrie des Pays<br />

Partenaires Méditerranéens », C<strong>on</strong>trat<br />

et Rapport de recherche Forum Euro-<br />

Mediterranéen des Instituts de Sciences<br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>omiques (FEMISE) (ME8/P7-<br />

4100/1B/97/0739-01) FEM21-21, soutenu<br />

par la Commissi<strong>on</strong> Européenne.<br />

MILNER C. et WRIGHT P. (1998), « Modelling<br />

labour market adjustment to trade libe-


alisati<strong>on</strong> in an industrialising ec<strong>on</strong>omy»,<br />

The Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Journal, 108, pp.<br />

508-528.<br />

NURMI S. (2004), “Openness to Trade<br />

and Employment Dynamics in Finnish<br />

Manufacturing”, Statistics Finland.<br />

Palméro S et Roux N (<strong>2005</strong>), dynamiques<br />

sectorielles et emploi au maroc, in<br />

étude <strong>Femise</strong> FEM22-22.<br />

Pennix R. (2004), “Integrati<strong>on</strong>: The Role<br />

of Communities, Instituti<strong>on</strong>s, and<br />

<strong>the</strong> State”, Migrati<strong>on</strong> Policy Institute,<br />

Washingt<strong>on</strong> DC<br />

RAUCH J. E. et WEINHOLD D. (1997), «<br />

Openness, specialisati<strong>on</strong>, end productivity<br />

growth in less developed countries<br />

», NBER Working Paper, 6131, March.<br />

RIZWANUL I. (2003), « Labour Market<br />

Policies, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Growth and Poverty<br />

Reducti<strong>on</strong> : Less<strong>on</strong>s and N<strong>on</strong>-less<strong>on</strong>s<br />

from <strong>the</strong> Comparative Experience of<br />

East, South-East and South Asia »,<br />

Issues in Employment and Poverty,<br />

Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper 8, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour<br />

Office, Geneva.<br />

SPIEZIA V. (2002), « Trade and employment :<br />

some empirical evidence », Paris, OCDE,<br />

draft for ILO project <strong>on</strong> Understanding<br />

Globalisati<strong>on</strong>, Employment and Poverty<br />

Reducti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

VIVARELLI M. (2002), “Globalisati<strong>on</strong>, skills<br />

and within-country inequality in developing<br />

countries”, Genève,<br />

Vostroknutova E., (2003), « Shadow Ec<strong>on</strong>omy,<br />

Rent-Seeking Activities and <strong>the</strong> Perils<br />

of Reinforcement of <strong>the</strong> Rule of Law<br />

», William Davids<strong>on</strong> Institute Working<br />

Paper no. 578<br />

WOOD A. (1995), « North South trade unemployment<br />

and inequality », Clarend<strong>on</strong><br />

Press Oxford, Chapitres 5-8.<br />

-96- -96-


ANNEXES<br />

Socio-ec<strong>on</strong>omic Indicators of MPs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . p.97<br />

Macro-ec<strong>on</strong>omic Indicators of MPs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . p.98<br />

FDI inflows . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . p.99<br />

Trade relati<strong>on</strong>s . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . p.100<br />

Modelisati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> impact of a South-South agreement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . p.101<br />

Modelisati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> impact of a North-South agreement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . p.102<br />

Modelisati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> impact of a multilateral liberalisati<strong>on</strong> . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . p.103<br />

-97-


-98-


Socio-ec<strong>on</strong>omic Indicators of MPs<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

-99-


Macro-ec<strong>on</strong>omic Indicators of MPs<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

-100-


FDI inflows<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

-101-


Hj is <strong>the</strong> country index, Xi = value of exports in product i , X = value of total exports of j country; 239 = number of product in SITC rev 2, 3 digits. The index is normalised to obtain value between<br />

0 and 1. The more low <strong>the</strong> value is, <strong>the</strong> more diversified <strong>the</strong> export structure is. The maximal c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> (index=1) means that <strong>the</strong> country exports <strong>on</strong>e product.<br />

[1] Calculated using <strong>the</strong> Herfindahl-Hirschmann index which allows a measure of <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> level of <strong>the</strong> exports of a country <strong>on</strong> a small group of products.<br />

Hj= i=1314 (xi/X)2 / (1/239)/(1 - (1/239))<br />

Source: Comtrade, calculati<strong>on</strong>s Institut de la Méditerranée<br />

Oil excluded Oil excluded Imports Exports 2003 2003 2003 2003 2003<br />

Algeria 7 947,6 14 537,2 7 878,4 338,2 2,75% 5,12% 6 590,0 -7 540,0 -6 046,0 2% 0,61<br />

Egypt 2 805,2 2 023,3 2 778,2 1 027,7 -5,94% 0,08% -782,0 -1 751,0 -1 388,0 39% 0,34<br />

Israel 13 955,3 8 423,4 13 906,2 8 420,8 -0,66% 4,01% -5 532,0 -5 485,0 -5 500,0 87% 0,22<br />

Jordan 1 428,1 89,3 1 425,3 89,3 1,94% -5,63% -1 339,0 -1 336,0 -1 094,0 42% 0,11<br />

Leban<strong>on</strong> 3 064,6 143,5 2 665,3 143,5 -1,29% 1,28% -2 921,0 -2 522,0 -2 038,0 67% 0,15<br />

Morocco 8 352,5 6 645,5 7 777,1 6 532,6 6,71% 10,88% -1 707,0 -1 244,0 -1 962,0 75% 0,20<br />

Syria 972,1 3 269,9 949,6 278,8 -7,12% -4,23% 2 298,0 -671,0 -626,0 5% 0,88<br />

Tunisia 7 353,1 5 877,7 6 926,7 5 341,1 3,01% 3,93% -1 475,0 -1 586,0 -1 397,0 84% 0,21<br />

Turkey 31 695,5 24 487,9 31 220,7 24 275,0 8,12% 10,55% -7 208,0 -6 946,0 -6 341,0 89% 0,14<br />

<br />

Trade relati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Average Annual Trade Growth<br />

Imports Exports Imports Exports rate, oil excluded 1995-2003 Overall trade Oil excluded<br />

Manufactured<br />

Products<br />

Manufactured<br />

Products share<br />

Exports<br />

C<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong><br />

[1]<br />

-102-<br />

<br />

Overall trade 2003 (milli<strong>on</strong> of dollars) Trade balances (milli<strong>on</strong> of dollars)<br />

Structure of trade<br />

<br />

Overall trade 2003 (milli<strong>on</strong> of dollars)<br />

Trade balances (milli<strong>on</strong> of dollars) Structure of trade<br />

Average Annual Trade Growth<br />

Exports<br />

Manufactured Manufactured<br />

Imports Exports Imports Exports rate, oil excluded 1995-2003 Overall trade Oil excluded<br />

C<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong><br />

Products Products share<br />

[1]<br />

Oil excluded Oil excluded Imports Exports 2003 2003 2003 2003 2003<br />

Algeria 57,8% 13 532,5 24 611,5 13 424,8 481,9 2,92% 0,93% 11 079,0 -12 943,0 -9 659,0 1% 0,60<br />

Egypt 20,7% 10 892,7 6 160,7 10 329,7 3 507,5 -1,43% 6,24% -4 732,0 -6 822,0 -3 414,0 25% 0,32<br />

Israel 60,0%* 34 210,9 31 782,7 30 451,9 31 644,6 1,67% 6,55% -2 428,0 1 193,0 1 871,0 96% 0,34<br />

Jordan 88,6% 5 653,2 3 081,6 4 720,3 3 074,1 4,90% 7,16% -2 572,0 -1 646,0 -1 354,0 66% 0,10<br />

Leban<strong>on</strong> 45,7% 7 167,5 1 523,9 6 046,8 1 520,4 2,41% 13,23% -5 644,0 -4 526,0 -3 561,0 51% 0,21<br />

Morocco 50,6% 13 730,6 8 777,2 11 514,6 8 547,7 5,74% 8,01% -4 953,0 -2 967,0 -3 240,0 46% 0,16<br />

Syria 50,4% 5 110,6 5 730,7 4 924,5 1 642,1 3,59% 6,96% 620,0 -3 282,0 -3 083,0 21% 0,61<br />

Tunisia 72,1% 10 146,7 7 354,4 9 454,5 6 721,9 3,23% 3,74% -2 792,0 -2 733,0 -2 050,0 68% 0,17<br />

Turkey 49,0% 69 339,7 47 252,8 57 764,8 46 272,6 8,05% 10,18% -22 087,0 -11 492,0 -7 046,0 82% 0,09<br />

<br />

* : GDP 2002


Modelisati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> impact of a South-South agreement<br />

Impact of a South-South agreement <strong>on</strong> various macroec<strong>on</strong>omic datas (in % of growth)<br />

Impact of a South-South agreement <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> sectors of producti<strong>on</strong> (previous level in billi<strong>on</strong><br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong> study, FEM22-36, CATT<br />

dollars and growth rate after 14 years)<br />

-103-


Modelisati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> impact of a North-South agreement<br />

Impact of a North-South agreement <strong>on</strong> various macroec<strong>on</strong>omic datas (in % of growth)<br />

Impact of a North-South agreement <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> external trade (previous level in billi<strong>on</strong> dollars<br />

and growth rate after 14 years)<br />

Impact of a North-South agreement <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> sectors of producti<strong>on</strong> (previous level in billi<strong>on</strong><br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong> study, FEM22-36, CATT<br />

dollars and growth rate after 14 years)<br />

-104-


Modélisati<strong>on</strong> de l’impact d’une libéralisati<strong>on</strong> multilatérale<br />

Impact of a multilateral liberalisati<strong>on</strong> agreement <strong>on</strong> various macroec<strong>on</strong>omic datas (in % of<br />

growth)<br />

Impact of a multilateral liberalisati<strong>on</strong> agreement <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> sectors of producti<strong>on</strong> (previous level<br />

Source: <strong>Femise</strong> study, FEM22-36, CATT<br />

in billi<strong>on</strong> dollars and growth rate after 14 years)<br />

-105-

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!