09.11.2013 Views

PLANNING FOR A SUSTAINABLE EUROPE? - TU Berlin

PLANNING FOR A SUSTAINABLE EUROPE? - TU Berlin

PLANNING FOR A SUSTAINABLE EUROPE? - TU Berlin

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>PLANNING</strong> <strong>FOR</strong> A <strong>SUSTAINABLE</strong> <strong>EUROPE</strong>?<br />

A CASE S<strong>TU</strong>DY OF EU TRANSPORT INFRASTRUC<strong>TU</strong>RE INVESTMENT<br />

POLICY IN THE CONTEXT OF EASTERN ENLARGEMENT<br />

by<br />

DEIKE PETERS<br />

A Dissertation submitted to the<br />

Graduate School-New Brunswick<br />

Rutgers, The State University of New Jersey<br />

in partial fulfillment of the requirements<br />

for the degree of<br />

Doctor of Philosophy<br />

Graduate Program in Urban Planning and Policy Development<br />

written under the direction of<br />

Prof. Susan S. Fainstein<br />

and approved by<br />

[Signature Susan S. Fainstein]<br />

[Signature Joanna Regulska]_<br />

[Signature Robert W. Lake]__<br />

[Signature John Pucher]_____<br />

New Brunswick, New Jersey<br />

January, 2003


2003<br />

DEIKE PETERS<br />

ALL RIGHTS RESERVED


ABSTRACT OF THE DISSERTATION<br />

Planning for a Sustainable Europe?<br />

A Case Study of EU Transport Infrastructure Policy<br />

in the Context of Eastern Enlargement<br />

by DEIKE PETERS<br />

Dissertation Director:<br />

Professor Susan S. Fainstein<br />

The study investigates the underlying rationalities of transport sector decisionmaking<br />

in Europe. The research seeks to explain discrepancies between the sustainability<br />

objectives expressed in EU Commission documents and the reality of EU-led transport<br />

sector investments. The study also shows how key defining concepts and justifications<br />

are adapted and/or modified in the specific context of EU pre-accession funding for<br />

Central Eastern Europe. The investigation is framed by six propositions which assume<br />

that sustainability remains an ill-defined concept; that ecological modernization is the<br />

dominant discourse in EU decision-making; that EU transport infrastructure investments<br />

are dominated by conflicting storylines; that decision-making is additionally complicated<br />

through varying decisional powers and challenges of multi-location politics; and that<br />

ecological modernization discourses tend to underestimate the local impacts of transport<br />

infrastructures.<br />

ii


A key conceptual innovation is provided by the notion of discursive frameworks.<br />

By distinguishing the five discursive frameworks of ecological modernization, reflexive<br />

modernization, communicative rationality, political economy and renunciation, the study<br />

develops a fivefold typology of sustainable policy-making in Europe. The dominant<br />

ecological modernization perspective is a modernist model of development that is<br />

relatively successful in integrating a variety of environmental concerns into its<br />

framework, but that nevertheless privileges competitiveness and economic growth over<br />

alternative development goals. In the case of pan-European transport infrastructures,<br />

such a growth-oriented perspective translates into a predominance of industry-favored<br />

investment storylines of missing links and bottlenecks over alternative storylines of<br />

spatial cohesion and polycentric development.<br />

However, while the European Round<br />

Table of Industrialists greatly influenced the development of the EU’s Trans-European<br />

Networks in the mid-1990s, decisions over the TEN extensions into Central Eastern<br />

Europe were much less dominated by multi-national corporate interests.<br />

The central summary insight of the study is the contextual discourse dilemma:<br />

planning and policy-making in modern capitalist democracies is dependent on developing<br />

universally applicable, integrative guiding visions such as sustainability to guide<br />

decision-making, yet these concepts only become useful tools for decision-makers if they<br />

are operationalized into concrete agendas which in turn translate into particular<br />

investment choices at the local level. Conversely, general discourses devoid of any<br />

applicability to local contexts are unlikely to gain widespread support.<br />

iii


ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS<br />

My thanks are due to the many people and institutions who have supported me in<br />

this multi-year, transatlantic endeavor. Rutgers’ Bloustein School of Planning and Public<br />

Policy provided a first-rate academic home base and much appreciated financial support<br />

for research and travel. Additional financial resources were provided through a Lincoln<br />

Land Dissertation Fellowship, a Fannie Mae AESOP Ph.D. travel grant and<br />

miscellaneous support from the Technical University of <strong>Berlin</strong>. The Salzburg Seminar<br />

provided a marvelous start into my research summer in 2000 and the German Academic<br />

Exchange Service (DAAD) provided a short-term Ph.D. grant during the final stages in<br />

2002. Susan Fainstein has truly been the best dissertation chair imaginable, and Bob<br />

Lake, John Pucher and Joanna Regulska all supplied useful advice at different stages of<br />

the dissertation. Ann Markusen, Don Krueckeberg and many of my fellow students in<br />

the urban planning program also provided excellent input during the formative stages of<br />

my research. Studying for theory exams with Laura, Marla and David was great fun and<br />

immensely enriched my perspective on urban and regional theory in general. Towards<br />

the end, Frank Fischer shared his own latest work for additional inspiration and provided<br />

welcome encouragement. Lynn Astorga provided crucial administrative and logistical<br />

support. At the legendary 1999 AESOP Ph.D. workshop in Norway, John Forester, Alex<br />

Fubini, Heather Campbell, Barry Needham, Aril Holt-Jensen and the rest of the Finse<br />

gang all helped me think through some initial conceptual problems – and have been an<br />

awesome peer group ever since. More generally, the annual AESOP and ACSP<br />

conferences have become invaluable forums for sharing my research and for learning<br />

from other planning academics. A special thanks goes to the members of the<br />

iv


Transnational Spatial Planning Track, in particular to Tim Richardson and Ole Jensen,<br />

who provided useful papers and literature leads, and to Andreas Faludi, who provided<br />

very encouraging comments on several parts of my work. I am also deeply indebted to<br />

the many people in Brussels, Warsaw, Budapest and elsewhere who took time out of their<br />

busy days to discuss their work with me. Having worked for ITDP, one of the world’s<br />

most successful sustainable transport advocacy organizations, for five years prior to<br />

doing my field research meant that many of the people I interviewed were already known<br />

to me as professional colleagues whose work I deeply respect and admire. Walter Hook<br />

deserves a very special thanks, both as the best boss imaginable and as a great friend.<br />

Since I left New York, the house at 544 Bergen has always been a wonderful home away<br />

from home for me. Thanks also to all the other folks who supplied bed & breakfast &<br />

entertainment during my many research trips – especially Magda in Brussels and Ferenc<br />

in Budapest. Finally, I owe a big thanks to my friends and colleagues here in <strong>Berlin</strong> for<br />

safely getting me through the more excruciating, final stages of the dissertation process. I<br />

am grateful to Max Welch Guerra for getting me to <strong>Berlin</strong> in the first place, and to Uwe<br />

Altrock, Jochen Hanisch, Simon Güntner, Sandra Huning, Jule Martinius, Harald<br />

Bodenschatz, Uwe-Jens Walther, Markus Hesse and many other university colleagues for<br />

much appreciated moral support and advice during the last two years. Thanks also to the<br />

Stammtisch and other dear friends who made sure that there was a fun-filled life outside<br />

the dissertation, to my family who always fully supported me even if that meant not<br />

seeing me nearly as much as they would have liked to in the last few years, and finally, to<br />

Charlie, whose love, support and late-night special caro coffees made all the difference in<br />

the end.<br />

v


TABLE OF CONTENTS<br />

Abstract<br />

Acknowledgements<br />

List of Tables<br />

List of Pictures<br />

List of Figures<br />

ii<br />

iv<br />

ix<br />

ix<br />

x<br />

1 Introduction 1<br />

1.1 In Search of a Sustainable Transport Policy for the New Europe 2<br />

1.2 Transport Infrastructure Investments Illustrate Key Dilemmas of Planning 4<br />

1.3 Situating the Study within the Existing Social Science Literature 6<br />

1.4 Some Preliminary Remarks on the Research Design and the<br />

Case Study Method 12<br />

1.5 The Unit(s) of Analysis 14<br />

1.6 Personal Motivations for Choosing European Transport Policy as an<br />

Area of Inquiry 18<br />

1.7 Initial Considerations: “Rhetoric vs. Reality” or “Realrationalität”? 20<br />

1.8 From General Research Questions to an Inquiry Structured Around Six<br />

Key Propositions 25<br />

1.9 Methods and Data Sources Used 33<br />

Part One: Theory-Building –<br />

Five Discursive Frameworks for a “Sustainable Europe”<br />

2 Transport, Development and Sustainability: First Approximations 40<br />

2.1 Introduction 41<br />

2.2 Transport and Economic Development 41<br />

2.3 “Sustainable Development” 57<br />

2.4 “Sustainable Transport” 66<br />

2.5 Sustainable Development and Sustainable Transport:<br />

Two Ill-Defined Concepts? 72<br />

3 Introducing the Notion of Discursive Frameworks 73<br />

3.1 Introduction: The Notion of a Dominant Discourse 74<br />

3.2 From Three Definitions of Sustainability to Five Discursive Frameworks 77<br />

3.3 Modernity and Modernization: Some (Meta-)Theoretical Considerations 79<br />

3.4 The Notion of Discursive Frameworks 93<br />

vi


4 Ecological Modernization and Its Alternatives: Five Discursive<br />

Frameworks for Sustainable EU Transport Policy 105<br />

4.1 Introduction 106<br />

4.2 Ecological Modernization: The Dominant Discursive Framework 109<br />

4.3 Reflexive Modernization 123<br />

4.4 Communicative Rationality 136<br />

4.5 Political Economy 146<br />

4.6 Renunciation 159<br />

4.7 Addendum: The “Institutionalist” Focus on EU Space and Governance 170<br />

4.8 Concluding Remarks 173<br />

Part Two: Rhetoric –<br />

EU Discourses on Transport Policy and Transport Infrastructure Investments<br />

5 EU Discourses on Sustainable Development and Sustainable Transport 175<br />

5.1 Introduction 176<br />

5.2 EU Discourses on Sustainable Development 178<br />

5.3 EU Discourses on Sustainable Transport 194<br />

5.4 EU Discourses on Sustainable Urban Development 208<br />

5.5 The EU’s Research Frameworks: Funding for the Eco-modernist Agenda 213<br />

5.6 Conclusions and Open Questions 216<br />

6 Three Leitbilder and Four Spatial Storylines for EU Transport<br />

Infrastructure Investments 219<br />

6.1 Introduction 220<br />

6.3 Three Overarching Leitbilder for EU Decision-Making 221<br />

6.2 Four Spatial Storylines For EU Transport Infrastructure Investments 231<br />

6.4 Conclusions: The Challenge of Prioritizing Investments 265<br />

Part Three: Realities –<br />

EU Transport Infrastructure Decision-Making<br />

in the Context of Eastern Enlargement<br />

7 EU Transport Infrastructure Plans for CEE: From 10 “Priority<br />

Corridors” to a “Backbone Network” for an Enlarged Union 271<br />

7.1 Introduction 272<br />

7.2 EU Plans and Programs for CEE Transport Infrastructures: Overview 276<br />

7.3 From the E-Routes to the Pan-European Transport Corridors 278<br />

7.4 The Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment (TINA) for CEE 285<br />

7.5 The Environmental Scoping Exercise on the Warsaw – Budapest Corridor 301<br />

7.6 Epilogue: The Proposed Hungarian Amendments to the TINA Network 305<br />

vii


7.7 Conclusions and Consequences 308<br />

8 EU Accession-Related Transport Funding for Poland & Hungary 313<br />

8.1 Introduction 314<br />

8.2 EU and IFI Transport Sector Assistance to Poland & Hungary Pre-ISPA 318<br />

8.3 A Precursor to Cohesion Funding? Overview of ISPA Priorities 324<br />

8.4 EU ISPA Transport Funding for Poland 330<br />

8.5 EU ISPA Transport Funding for Hungary 342<br />

8.6 Concluding Remarks on the EU’s ISPA Transport Program 357<br />

9 Local Dimensions of Sustainability: A Case Study of the Budapest Ring<br />

Road M0 362<br />

9.1 Introduction: The Significance of the M0 Case Study 363<br />

9.2 Description of the M0 Including a Chronology of International Funding 364<br />

9.3 Arguments For and Against the M0 Ring Road: A Typology 370<br />

9.4 Local and International Protests Against the Northern Section of the M0 375<br />

9.5 Risk-Rational Concerns: Is Brussels Financing Urban Sprawl in Budapest? 381<br />

9.6 Conclusions 397<br />

Part Four:<br />

Conclusions & Appendices<br />

10 The Dilemmas of Planning for a Sustainable Europe 401<br />

10.1 Planning, Sustainability and the Contextual Discourse Dilemma 402<br />

10.2 Summary of Previous Chapter Contents and Conclusions 405<br />

10.3 Cross-Cutting Conclusions on “Sustainable” Decision-Making 414<br />

10.4 Suggestions for Better Transport Decision-Making in Europe 426<br />

10.5 Outlook: Suggestions for Further Research 433<br />

Annexes, Glossary, Bibliography, & Curriculum Vita 435<br />

Annex A1 Overview of IFI Lending to Poland and Hungary until 2001 436<br />

Annex A2 List of Key Contacts 441<br />

Annex A3 List of Relevant Conferences, Seminars and Writings 446<br />

Annotated Glossary of Terms, Acronyms and Abbreviations 449<br />

Bibliography 455<br />

Curriculum Vita 483<br />

viii


LIST OF TABLES<br />

Tables<br />

Page<br />

1.1 The Three Levels of EU Decision-Making 12<br />

1.2 How the Six Propositions Relate to the Overall Structure of the Study 30<br />

2.1. The “Rio Cluster” of UN Summits, Conferences, and Conventions 60<br />

2.2 The OECD’s Sustainable Transport Principles 71<br />

3.1 Five Discursive Frameworks for Sustainable Policy-Making 77<br />

4.1 Five Discursive Frameworks for Transport Planning & Policy-Making 108<br />

4.2 Comparing Instrumental and Communicative Rationality 145<br />

4.3 “Brown” Agenda versus “Green” Agenda Environmental Policy 149<br />

4.4 The Eight Points of Deep Ecology 161<br />

5.1 Key EU Statements on Sustainability, Transport & Spatial Development 177<br />

5.2 Transport-relevant Research funded under the EU Fifth Framework Program 215<br />

6.1 Overview of EU Transport Infrastructure Investment Storylines 236<br />

7.1 Key Initiatives Related to EU Transport-Infrastructure Investments in CEE 278<br />

8.1 Per Country Allocation for ISPA Transport Grants 325<br />

8.2 Overview of ISPA Transport Grants to Poland 339<br />

8.3 The Széchenyi Plan’s Railway Modernization Program 348<br />

8.4 The Széchenyi Plan’s Expressway Construction Program 349<br />

8.5 Overview of ISPA Transport Grants to Hungary 355<br />

9.1 Main Arguments for & Objections against the M0 Ring Road Plans 374<br />

10.1 A Two-Dimensional ‘Who-Benefits?’ - Matrix for the M0 Case Study 431<br />

A.1 EIB Transport Loans to Poland (1990-2001) 436<br />

A.2 EIB Transport Loans to Hungary (1990-2001) 437<br />

A.3 EBRD and IBRD Transport Loans to Poland (1990-2001) 438<br />

A.4 EBRD and IBRD Transport Loans in Hungary (1989-2001) 439<br />

LIST OF PIC<strong>TU</strong>RES<br />

Pictures<br />

Page<br />

9.1 Construction of the Northern Section of the M0 Ring Road with the<br />

Káposztásmegzer II Housing Estate in the Background 377<br />

9.2 Big Box Retail along the M1/7 & M0 Highways in Budaörs: IKEA & Auchan 390<br />

9.3 New Single-family Homes in the Environmentally Sensitive Hills of Budaörs 390<br />

ix


LIST OF FIGURES<br />

Figures<br />

Page<br />

1.1 Key Stakeholders in Pan-European Transport Policy-Making 16<br />

1.2 European Policy-Making as Interpreted as Multi-Level Governance 17<br />

1.3 European Policy-Making as Interpreted as Multi-Location Politics 17<br />

2.1 The EU and the Nordic Countries Compared 53<br />

2.2 The Three Dimensions of Sustainable Development 66<br />

4.1 Environmental Costs/Risks of Transport as presented by the EEA 136<br />

6.1 Transport Grants within the EU-15 by Mode 230<br />

6.2 Cohesion Fund Transport Grants by Country and Mode (1993-1997) 230<br />

6.3 The Blue Banana I: An Image Ingrained 249<br />

6.4 Blue Banana Maps Focusing on Peripheral Regions & Urban Linkages 249<br />

6.5 The Blue Banana versus a European Bunch of Grapes 250<br />

6.6 Missing Links I: The ERT Vision (1984) 256<br />

6.7 Missing Links III: The EU TEN Priority Projects (1994) 256<br />

6.8 Missing Links III: The ECMT Version (1986) 259<br />

7.1 The Pan-European Transport Network with the 10 Helsinki Corridors 280<br />

7.2 Pan-European Transport Corridor IV – Road Sector 284<br />

7.3 Pan-European Transport Corridor IV – Rail Sector 284<br />

7.4 TINA Road Network 288<br />

7.5 TINA Rail Network 289<br />

7.6 TINA Network Poland 290<br />

7.7 TINA Network Hungary 291<br />

7.8 EU Data on Transport Infrastructure Investment as Percentage of GDP 297<br />

7.9 Proposed Hungarian TINA Road, Port and Airport Amendments 307<br />

7.10 Proposed Hungarian TINA Rail Amendments 307<br />

7.11 Hungary’s Motorway Investment Plan 2000-2010 308<br />

7.12 Share of international road freight traffic measured in ton-kilometers 310<br />

7.13 National Goods by Distance Traveled in the EU and CEE 310<br />

8.1 PHARE Funds for Hungary and Poland per Sector 1990-97 (in MECU) 323<br />

8.2 EU Transport Grants to CEEC pre-ISPA (Phare 1990-97, LISF 1998-99) 324<br />

8.3 The Rise of Road-Based Freight Transport in Hungary (1980-1994) 343<br />

9.1 The Budapest Ring Road M0 365<br />

9.2 New construction of warehouse/logistic facilities along the M0, M1, M7 391<br />

9.4 Location of the seven largest warehousing centers in the Budapest area 391<br />

9.5-6 Auchan Hypermarket next to the EIB- & Phare-funded Section of the M0 392<br />

9.7 Residential Suburbanization in the Budapest Agglomeration (1900-2005) 393<br />

9.8 The Density Pattern of the City of Budapest 394<br />

9.8 Budapest’s “Strategic Zones” acc. to its Urban Development Strategy 396<br />

A.1 TINA Needs 2000-2015 vs. IFI TINA Network Loans 1990-2000 440<br />

x


1<br />

Printed Thursday, October 31, 2002<br />

Last Revised on September 15, 2002<br />

CHAPTER 1<br />

Introduction<br />

1.1 In Search of a Sustainable Transport Policy for the New Europe .................................2<br />

1.2 Transport Infrastructure Investments Illustrate Key Dilemmas of Planning................4<br />

1.3 Situating the Study within the Existing Social Science Literature ................................6<br />

1.4 Some Preliminary Remarks on the Research Design and the Case Study Method...12<br />

1.5 The Unit(s) of Analysis....................................................................................................14<br />

1.6 Personal Motivations for Choosing the Area of Inquiry ..............................................18<br />

1.7 Initial Considerations: “Rhetoric versus Reality” or “Realrationalität”? ..................20<br />

1.8 From a Set of General Research Questions to Six Key Propositions..........................25<br />

1.8.1 The Ill-Defined Concept Proposition.........................................................................26<br />

1.8.2 The Dominant Discourse Proposition........................................................................26<br />

1.8.3 The Conflicting Storylines Proposition .....................................................................28<br />

1.8.4 The Decisional Power Proposition.............................................................................29<br />

1.8.5 The Challenges of Multi-Location Politics Proposition...........................................29<br />

1.8.6 The Local Impacts Proposition...................................................................................31<br />

1.8.7 Summarizing the Organization of the Study.............................................................31<br />

1.9 Methods and Data Sources Used ....................................................................................33<br />

1.9.1 Document Review .......................................................................................................35<br />

1.9.2 Interviews......................................................................................................................36<br />

1.9.3 General Statistical Data ...............................................................................................37


2<br />

1.1 In Search of a Sustainable Transport Policy for the New Europe<br />

What changes must now occur, in our way of looking at things, in our notions! Even<br />

the elementary concepts of time and space have begun to vacillate. Space is killed by<br />

the railways. I feel as if the mountains and forests of all countries were advancing on<br />

Paris. Even now, I can smell the German linden trees, the North Sea's breakers are<br />

rolling against my door.<br />

Heinrich Heine's “Tremendous Foreboding” in response to the opening of the Paris-<br />

Rouen rail link in 1854 (cited in Harvey 1996)<br />

The history of modern societies can be read as a history of their acceleration.<br />

J. Steiner (cited in Spiekermann and Wegener 1994)<br />

The advent of the European Union and the breakup of the Soviet Union in the<br />

1990s have brought profound new challenges to all levels of planning and policy making<br />

across the European continent. The European Union is now under enormous pressure to<br />

uphold its self-proclaimed goals of “harmonious, balanced development, sustainable<br />

growth, economic and social cohesion, improved quality of life and solidarity between<br />

member states” 1 while at the same time preparing ten Central and Eastern European<br />

(CEE) transition countries for accession.<br />

One of the key issues within this challenge of creating an ever-expanding<br />

“Sustainable Europe” is the upgrading, expansion and optimization of transport<br />

infrastructures. John Ross (1998:xii) found transport to be “an unusually fertile, though<br />

often overlooked, subject in the firmament of European studies.” The stakes for investing<br />

in the “right” kinds of transport and land use systems are especially high in the transition<br />

countries, where systemic changes are the most dramatic, motorization rates the highest,<br />

infrastructure needs the greatest, and where EU accession funds and other international<br />

funding are most likely to make a critical difference in sustainability outcomes.


3<br />

In today’s globalized world, many of the most important decisions for planning and<br />

policy-making are no longer taken at the national or at the local level, but involve several<br />

nations at once. In many ways, the formation of the EU itself can be read as a response<br />

to global competition. When it comes to influencing policy and planning decisions in the<br />

key areas of concern in this study, i.e. transport infrastructures and urban/regional<br />

development, the EU has continually expanded its reach, quite in contrast to its selfimposed<br />

principle of subsidiarity. Although transport did not really become an area of<br />

high EU politics until the early 90s, developments since the passing of the Maastricht<br />

Treaty have been dramatic, concerning both initiatives under the auspices of the<br />

Directorate General for Transport (now Transport and Energy) as well as transportrelated<br />

funding under the auspices of the Directorate General for Regional Development.<br />

Additionally, since the passing of the European Spatial Development Perspective (ESDP)<br />

in 1997, one must now also consider the EU a de facto spatial planning institution.<br />

Buunk (1999) recently convincingly argued that the EU Trans-European Transport<br />

Network (TENs) can be considered “the first spatial concept in European policies.” Any<br />

attempt to direct transport-infrastructure investments at a supra-national Pan-European<br />

level, while certainly qualifying as a spatial planning exercise (also see below), is<br />

certainly a much more complicated task than “traditional” urban or regional planning, for<br />

several obvious reasons:<br />

First of all, not one, but many (state-like) actors are involved: the European Union<br />

and individual nation-states. Among the latter, crucial differences are likely to exist<br />

between member states and applicant countries. With plans and policies being<br />

international in scope, they necessarily have to transgress national boundaries, physical as<br />

1 Article 2 of the 1992 Maastricht Treaty on European Union


4<br />

well as ideological ones. Serious geopolitical interests are likely to shape the process,<br />

depending on the different power relationships among the various actors involved. Given<br />

the vast geographical scope and sheer magnitude of the issue, it is also much less clear<br />

who “the public” is in this case. Concrete locational conflicts and ownership struggles<br />

over particular stretches of land are unlikely to influence the decision-making process in<br />

Brussels much, although they might certainly come to the fore at the individual project<br />

level.<br />

1.2 Transport Infrastructure Investments Illustrate Key Dilemmas of Planning<br />

A human right, a human pleasure, an economic resource and a servant of economic<br />

activity: transport is many things to all people.<br />

European Commission, Directorate General for Transport1994:1<br />

The decision to choose transport infrastructure decision-making as the key focus<br />

of this investigation was not a random one, but followed a strong conviction on my part<br />

that struggles over transport infrastructure investment decisions best illustrate the central<br />

dilemma of public policy and planning in modern capitalist democracies. That is:<br />

planners and policy makers, and ”state agents” more generally are always caught between<br />

two central and often contradictory objectives. On one hand, they administer<br />

infrastructure systems and services for the “public good,” thereby providing the so-called<br />

“legitimation functions” of the modern welfare state (Offe and Keane 1984). On the<br />

other hand, they facilitate and support the activities of private sector agents in order to<br />

advance capitalist development objectives. In the Anglophone planning literature, this<br />

central contradiction was perhaps best summarized by Foglesong who is worth quoting at<br />

length here:


5<br />

Following Offe’s analysis, it can be postulated that capitalism is caught in a search for<br />

a decision process, a method of policy-making than can produce decisions<br />

corresponding with capital’s political and economic interests. Politically, this decision<br />

process must be capable of insulating state decision making from the claims and<br />

considerations of the numerically larger class of noncapitalists, a task made difficult<br />

by the formally democratic character of the state. Economically, this decision process<br />

must be capable of producing decisions that facilitate the accumulation and circulation<br />

of capital (for example, promoting the reproduction of labor power and coordinating<br />

the buildup of local infrastructure), a function that the market fails to perform and that<br />

capitalists do not (necessarily) know how to perform. Both of these problems are<br />

captured in the concept of the capitalist-democracy contradiction.<br />

(Foglesong 1996:174-5)<br />

Of course, Foglesong’s excellent study was written from the particular perspective<br />

of structural Marxism, as applied to the US, which makes it problematic not only in the<br />

sense that the analysis is limited to the specific context of US urban planning in the 19 th<br />

and 20 th centuries, but also in that the key question of agency often slips from his view.<br />

Fogelsong’s arguments often seem overly deterministic, giving planners and policymakers<br />

too much credit for anticipating the needs of capital and actually being able to<br />

implement plans accordingly. His analysis nevertheless remains relevant to the challenge<br />

of planning and funding a European-wide transport infrastructure system.<br />

To be sure, transport infrastructure decision-making can never be analyzed in<br />

isolation. Any thorough investigation of the European Union’s ability to formulate a<br />

transport agenda that is consistent with its own Maastricht promise of sustainable<br />

development will also need to consider the relationship of transport policies and plans to<br />

other EU policy-making areas, notably in the areas of environment, regional<br />

development, spatial planning and enlargement.


6<br />

1.3 Situating the Study within the Existing Social Science Literature<br />

Changes in planning and policy discourse are not always congruent with changes<br />

in policies and development trends (see e.g. Filion’s 1999 local case study on Toronto).<br />

Nevertheless, “the argumentative turn in policy analysis and planning” (Fischer and<br />

Forester 1993) continues relatively unchallenged. Over the past three decades, all social<br />

scientists, no matter whether they are considered to be working in a modernist (e.g.<br />

Habermasian), post-modernist (e.g. Foucauldian), or anti-modernist (e.g. Deep Ecology)<br />

framework, have learned to pay greater attention to discourses and rhetoric. 2 As Fainstein<br />

(2000:451) recently summarized for the academic discipline of planning:<br />

The past decade has witnessed a reinvigoration of theoretical discussion within the<br />

discipline of planning. Inspired by postmodernist cultural critique and by the move<br />

among philosophers away from logical positivism toward a substantive concern with<br />

ethics and public policy, planning theorists have reframed their debates over methods<br />

and programs to encompass issues of discourse and inclusiveness.<br />

The parallel existence of different “discourses” - or rather, as I clarify in my<br />

theory chapters: of different “discursive frameworks” - all display varying levels of<br />

optimism with regard to the merits and prospects of rational decision-making. This<br />

indicates that the social sciences are fundamentally in need of redefining themselves.<br />

Especially when it comes to environmental questions, traditional disciplinary distinctions<br />

are easily blurred. Twenty years ago, most social scientists concerned about the macro<br />

issues of (sustainable) development and globalization probably would have been content<br />

to self-describe themselves as economists, political scientists, geographers or perhaps<br />

2 Greater attention to discourse and language is typically seen as a postmodern phenomenon. Yet it can equally well<br />

be interpreted as a decidedly modernist trait. In the Condition of Postmodernity, David Harvey reminds us that in<br />

facing the practical dilemmas of implementing the modernist project, “modernism, from its very beginning,<br />

therefore, became preoccupied with language, with finding some special mode of representation of eternal truths”<br />

(Harvey 1989:20).


7<br />

sociologists. Today, there is a cacophony of voices from departments of public policy<br />

and administration; urban, regional, and rural sociology; industrial ecology; economic<br />

and human geography, environmental psychology, cultural philosophy, international<br />

political economy; urban and spatial planning, etc, all of them contributing to the<br />

theorization of concepts such as development, modernization and globalization in their<br />

own way, and all of them employing the term sustainability in very different ways.<br />

Interdisciplinary concepts such as sustainability demonstrate the confines of writing<br />

within dominant the body of discourse of certain social science disciplines. Bob Jessop<br />

and Ngai-Ling Sum (2001:89) recently summarized the dilemma as follows:<br />

Neither co-author identifies with a single discipline. … We are not alone in refusing<br />

disciplinary boundaries and decrying some of their effects. Indeed, among the most<br />

exciting recent intellectual developments in the social sciences is the increasing<br />

commitment to transcending these boundaries to understand better the complex<br />

interconnections within and across the natural and social worlds. … [We witness] the<br />

gradual decomposition and/or continuing crisis of orthodox disciplines [and] the rise<br />

of new transdisciplinary fields of study and a commitment to post-disciplinarity. This<br />

[among other factors] is reflected in the growing critical interest in the history of the<br />

social sciences, their grounding in Enlightenment thought, their links to state<br />

formation in Europe and the USA, as well as to capitalist economic development and<br />

their differential articulation of modernity.<br />

This is indeed an exciting development and not necessarily a problem in and of<br />

itself. Interestingly, for the sub-discipline of political economy, Jessop and Sum<br />

ascertain a growing influence “of intellectual figures with no clear disciplinary identity<br />

whose work is influential across many disciplines” (p.90). 3<br />

Regardless of this emerging<br />

interdisciplinary, or perhaps indeed post-disciplinary dialogue, at present, the great<br />

variation in the ideological (and also methodological) approaches in the social sciences<br />

3 Interestingly, they list not only figures such as Michel Foucault, Anthony Giddens or Jürgen Habermas,<br />

but also scholars with a distinctly urban focus in their work, such as David Harvey, Manuel Castells and


8<br />

makes it much more difficult to draw up consistent and clearly delimited research<br />

projects, especially when they are to contain the term “sustainability”. We also have to<br />

keep in mind the important distinction between natural science and social science<br />

research and the methodological challenges each faces.<br />

Although the scale of this study is Pan-European and moves far beyond the local<br />

and the urban to include regional, national, and international perspectives on decisionmaking,<br />

the analytic tools employed and the intellectual roots that inspire the writing<br />

come from an urban theory tradition. That is: The questions that motivated me to study<br />

the European Union are largely the same that motivate urban theorists to study urban<br />

governments. The central issue is how to analyze and interpret the ever-present contrast<br />

between decision-makers rhetoric of the benign and universally beneficial impact of their<br />

policies and plans and the reality of winners and losers that those decisions always entail.<br />

To take but one example: in his chapter “How to study urban political power,” New York<br />

political scientist John Mollenkopf (1996:264) asks the question “How can we develop a<br />

vocabulary for analyzing politics and state action that reconciles the political system’s<br />

independent impact on social outcomes with its observed systemic bias in favor of<br />

capital?” In the answer he gives, he stresses “three interrelated levels”: a) how economic<br />

and social conditions shape the state’s capacity to act, b) how the ‘rules of the game’ of<br />

politics shape competition among interests and actors to construct a dominant political<br />

coalition and c) how economic and social change and political competition shape interest<br />

mobilization. These levels are just as relevant for studying EU power and decisionmaking<br />

as they are for studying US urban politics. In particular, the approach taken in<br />

Saskia Sassen. Most commonly, those authors are simply identified as “social theorists” (see e.g. Murphy<br />

2000:1).


9<br />

this dissertation owes much to (urban) regime theory. 4<br />

The de facto multi-level<br />

governance character of EU decision-making of course makes it difficult to identify<br />

governing coalitions (a key focus of regime theory analyses), and this is in fact not the<br />

exclusive aim of my study. Nevertheless, I take many lessons from regime theory<br />

scholars. I draw particular inspiration from the groundedness of regime theory analyses,<br />

which employ detailed examination of process and outcomes within particular locales.<br />

Thus, in their efforts to tease out the particular way in which “complexity and<br />

fragmentation limit the capacity of the state as an agency of authority or control” (Stoker<br />

1995), regime scholars have presented rich local case studies, thereby helping to elevate<br />

this formerly often underappreciated method of scientific inquiry into higher academic<br />

esteem. I likewise view the case study approach as the most appropriate way to approach<br />

my inquiry (also see below).<br />

In the end, the larger theoretical perspective of this dissertation is informed by a<br />

political economy 5 approach concerned with long-term environmental sustainability and<br />

social equity objectives. My general conception of the European Union is as a supra-<br />

4 Regime theory emerged out of the U.S. context in the 1980s as a new approach to study urban political power that<br />

helped analysts to move beyond existing divides between pluralist approaches that see decision-making power and<br />

influence largely as fragmented and decentralized on the one hand and elitist and/or structuralist approaches that see<br />

them as being dominated by a select group on the other hand. The two had increasingly been constructed as polar<br />

opposites within urban political theory. Regime theory, however, as Stoker (1995:55) notes,<br />

emphasizes the interdependence of governmental and non-governmental forces in meeting economic<br />

and social challenges[,] focuses attention upon the problem of cooperation and coordination between<br />

governmental and non-governmental actors. … It directs attention away from a narrow focus on power<br />

as an issue of social control towards an understanding of power expressed through social production.<br />

In this sense, my study can be read as an attempt to take certain insights of urban regime theory away from the<br />

particular U.S. and urban-centered focus in which they first emerged towards the (admittedly significantly different)<br />

political context of EU decision-making.<br />

5 I use the term “political-economy” here in its wider social science meaning signifying a general approach<br />

that sees political and economic forces as inextricably linked. I am not proposing to do an explicitly<br />

Marxist analysis, nor do I wish to imply that my argument is explicitly following Keohane and Hoffmann’s<br />

(1991) so-called “political-economy hypothesis” (also see McCormick 1996:22) that EU institutional<br />

change and integration are first and foremost a response to global economic pressures. Also see Chapters 3<br />

and 4.


10<br />

national institution whose legitimacy as a planning and policy-making body is founded<br />

on a mix of economic opportunism and geopolitical strategizing. While it would be<br />

foolish to attempt to summarize the vast academic literature on the European Union in a<br />

few paragraphs, at least a cursory revealing of scholarly preferences is in order.<br />

Theories of the EU can be broadly divided between (realist) intergovernmentalist<br />

perspectives that continue to stress the role of member-states in EU policy-making<br />

(Moravcsik 1991; Moravcsik 1998; Peterson and Bomberg 1999) and institutionalist<br />

accounts that consider a broader range of actors and focus on different levels and forms<br />

of decision-making at the EU. The latter accounts are variously used to support theories<br />

of (neo)-functionalism (Haas 1958), federalism (Scharpf 1999) or most generally, of<br />

multi-level governance (see e.g. Marks, Hooghe et al. 1996; Bache 1998; Hix 1998).<br />

Intergovernmentalist accounts are partially correct in asserting that national-level politics<br />

continue to play a significant role in shaping European Union policies and programs.<br />

However, much more attention indeed needs to be paid to the specific institutional setup<br />

and the agency of particular interest groups to truly understand likely outcomes in<br />

particular policy areas, especially in the case of transport.<br />

Since this study is conceptualized much more within a urban<br />

theory/planning/public policy tradition than within the political science sub-field of<br />

European studies, my research should not primarily be understood as an explicit<br />

contribution to the rapidly evolving institutionalist literature on multi-level governance in<br />

the EU.<br />

Nevertheless, I find Peterson and Bomberg’s (1999) three-fold model of EU<br />

decision-making levels a very useful framework for analyzing different levels of EU<br />

transport decision-making. Table 1.1 presents an adaptation of their model to the


11<br />

particular context of EU transport policy. Note that according to this model, most of the<br />

decision-making processes I analyze are either policy-setting or policy-shaping decisions.<br />

The Trans-European Networks and the Pan-European transport corridors, however,<br />

should be regarded as history-making decisions, since they were decided upon at the<br />

ministerial level. This history-making character of the TEN and TEN-extensions is rather<br />

important for my overall analysis.<br />

In the end, I strongly support the notion that there is not one single best “grand<br />

theory” that can explain all EU decision-making but that “different kinds of theories are<br />

appropriate for different parts of the EU puzzle” (Sandholtz 1996, quoted in Peterson and<br />

Bomberg 1999:9). To be sure, the subject of eastern enlargement, as well as the political,<br />

economic, social, and environmental costs and benefits associated with it, are all<br />

currently the subject of intense discussion among EU scholars (see e.g. Avery and<br />

Cameron 1998; Grabbe and Hughes 1998; Redmond and Rosenthal 1998; Henderson<br />

1999; Mannin 1999). However, most scholars would agree that by now, “the EU has<br />

taken steps towards eastern enlargement which make the process irreversible” (Peterson<br />

and Bomberg 1999:1). For the purposes of this study, I therefore work from a rather<br />

pragmatic, pro-integrationist perspective that sees the accession of at least first-tier CEE<br />

states like Hungary and Poland into the EU as both a politically desirable and attainable<br />

goal.


12<br />

Table 1.1: The Three Levels of EU Decision-Making<br />

Level Type of<br />

Decision<br />

Case Study<br />

Example<br />

Bargaining<br />

mode<br />

Type of<br />

Rationality<br />

Super-<br />

Systemic<br />

historymaking<br />

TENcorridors<br />

intergovernmental<br />

Political<br />

Systemic<br />

policysetting<br />

White<br />

Papers<br />

interinstitutional<br />

Political;<br />

Technocratic<br />

Sub-<br />

Systemic<br />

policyshaping<br />

Phare;<br />

ISPA<br />

resource<br />

exchange<br />

Technocratic;<br />

Consensual<br />

Source: adapted from Peterson and Bomberg 1999:9<br />

1.4 Some Preliminary Remarks on the Research Design and the Case Study Method<br />

All inquiry is structured around one or several research questions. Yet there are<br />

several ways of organizing and documenting social science research. Formulating a<br />

series of ex ante hypotheses and developing a step-by-step research design that will<br />

subsequently either clearly confirm or validate these hypotheses is a common, and<br />

perhaps the most accepted way to organize original research, especially in the Anglo-<br />

American sphere of influence. Documentation of such research designs will typically<br />

portray results as being the (necessary) consequences of a stringent logical construct that<br />

was clearly formulated prior to beginning the fieldwork. A variant, more explorative, and<br />

perhaps more continental European way is to formulate more general research questions<br />

and propositions, and to document the process of realization that guided and propelled the<br />

investigation towards the key insights. The latter is also more typical of case study<br />

investigations. It leaves less room for retrospective palliation of the research process.<br />

Revisions to the research questions, designs and the process of data collection, as well as<br />

intellectual cul-de-sacs need to be made somewhat more transparent, rather than glossed


13<br />

over and forgotten. Of course, results might appear less imperative and less “neat,” so to<br />

speak. However, documenting research in this way seems to me to be both more truthful<br />

and more rewarding. 6<br />

As King, Keohane and Verba (1994:19 ) note in their authoritative<br />

book on Designing Social Inquiry:<br />

Social scientists often begin research with a considered design, collect some data, and<br />

draw conclusions. But this process is rarely a smooth one and is not always best done<br />

in this order: conclusions rarely follow easily from a research design and data<br />

collected in accordance with it.<br />

Meanwhile, Robert Yin’s (1994) best-selling book Case Study Research has done<br />

much to redeem case study research from being regarded as a useful yet scientifically<br />

slightly dubious approach, to firmly establish it as a valid way of doing social science<br />

research. Case studies like the present one are particularly applicable whenever the<br />

investigation “emphasizes the importance of situating practices in their specific<br />

circumstances” (Healey, Khakee et al. 1999). Additionally, my study can also be viewed<br />

as a variant of policy research, and as Majchzak (1984:58) observes, policy research<br />

often operates “at the boundaries of research methodology” and “there is no single,<br />

comprehensive methodology for doing the technical analysis of policy research.”<br />

Finally, as Yin (1994:1) notes, “in general, case studies are the preferred strategy when<br />

‘how’ or ‘why’ questions are being posed, when the investigator has little control over<br />

events, and when the focus is on a contemporary phenomenon within some real-life<br />

context.” This is certainly the case in the present study. Case studies’ distinctive place in<br />

(evaluation) research is to “explain the causal links in real-life interventions that are too<br />

complex for the survey or experimental strategies” (Yin 1994: 15).<br />

6 I am grateful to Uwe-Jens Walther and the participants of his graduate research seminar at the <strong>TU</strong> <strong>Berlin</strong> for<br />

encouraging me to clearly avow myself an adherent of the latter, more openly investigative approach.


14<br />

Case studies are often accused of subjectivity and selectivity since they are not<br />

“replicable” science in the strict sense of the word. Non-replicability, however, is an<br />

intrinsic, almost necessary feature of all qualitative work dealing with complex topics.<br />

All research that relies upon the gathering, selection and evaluation of large amounts of<br />

qualitative information is in some way non-replicable. In my case the vastness of the<br />

information impacting on my subject area was especially overwhelming. Yet there is no<br />

better solution to this problem than for the researcher to be diligent about documenting<br />

her primary and secondary sources, about the (construct, internal and external) validity<br />

and reliability of her research design, and finally, for the reader to give her the benefit of<br />

the doubt as far as any purposeful distortion of facts, events or discourses is concerned. 7<br />

1.5 The Unit(s) of Analysis<br />

The general unit of analysis in this study is the European Union, or rather its<br />

development approach, which the EU purports to be “sustainable development.” I use<br />

the sub-area of transport infrastructure investment decision-making in the context of<br />

enlargement as my specific case study area, i.e. sub-unit of analysis. In the end, as is<br />

typical for many case studies, the overall case study review is really comprised of several<br />

sub-case studies evaluating different EU policies, programs and actual projects related to<br />

the topic. With regard to EU institutions, my view is mostly focused on the work and<br />

workings of the European Commission, which is the only EU institution vested with<br />

7 Recurring media reports about falsified results in medical research have taught us that even the supposedly more<br />

objective natural sciences are not immune to politicking and outright deceit. But in the end, reductionism is not an<br />

option for the social sciences, since quantitative research alone will never yield relevant answers to today’s most<br />

pressing social and environmental problems.


15<br />

formal agenda-setting powers. More precisely, I trace the policies, programs and<br />

activities of those Commission Directorates-General - the Commission’s equivalents of<br />

ministries - which are most relevant for sustainable transport decision-making (i.e. DG<br />

Transport and Energy, DG Regional Policy, DG Environment and DG Enlargement).<br />

Note, however, that especially when it comes to “history-making” decisions on EU<br />

transport policy (also see Table 1.1. above), additional stakeholders (i.e. the EU Council,<br />

the Council of Ministers, the Parliament, national governments, and, last but not least,<br />

lobby groups) enter the picture as important decision-makers. Given necessary limits to<br />

the scope of the study, I chose Poland and Hungary as two front-runner EU candidate<br />

countries that might best illustrate key issues with regard to enlargement-related EU<br />

transport policies and programs. Figure 1.1 provides a general overview of the relevant<br />

stakeholders in Pan-European transport policy making as well as the key Pan-European<br />

transport plans and programs which I investigate in this study.<br />

With regard to the relationship between the different stakeholders, I agree with<br />

Helen Wallace that European policy-making is best interpreted as a realm of multilocation<br />

politics. Wallace (2000:73-74) makes the following crucial point (which I argue<br />

holds for Central Europe as well):<br />

The EU policy-process is frequently described as a multi-level process. … Here,<br />

however, I make a more extended observation about different locations of policymaking.<br />

In western Europe we can observe policies being made in many different<br />

locations. Please note that here I deliberately avoid the term ‘level’, which implies a<br />

hierarchy. Instead, I suggest, in a more open-ended way, that European policies are<br />

constructed in locations that vary between, at one extreme, the local, and, at the other<br />

extreme, the global. … This is an extraordinary array of locations. It provides those<br />

demanding and supplying policy with a multiplicity of options for pursuing their<br />

objectives and for developing capabilities. Nor does one location clearly separate<br />

itself from others. On the contrary, they overlap.<br />

[Emphasis in the original]


16<br />

In adapting this concept of “multi-locationality” to my case study, figures 1.2 and<br />

1.3 visualize the difference between an interpretation of EU (transport) policy-making as<br />

multi-locational politics and an interpretation as multi-level governance.<br />

Finally, note that throughout the study, I increasingly move from a larger to a<br />

smaller scale, beginning with global and Pan-European discourses on sustainable<br />

transport development and ending with a review of the national-, regional- and even<br />

local-level implications of these discourses for transport infrastructure funding in the<br />

candidate countries.<br />

Figure 1.1 Key Stakeholders in Pan-European Transport Policy-Making<br />

Source: Own compilation. Please consult the glossary for explanations on abbreviations.


17<br />

Figure 1.2 European Policy-Making Interpreted as Multi-Level Governance<br />

Pan-European &<br />

International Organizations:<br />

OECD/ECMT, UNECE, etc.<br />

Cities<br />

Regions<br />

EU Member Countries<br />

Cities<br />

Regions<br />

Candidate Countries<br />

European Union<br />

Other Stakeholders:<br />

IFIs, NGOs, etc.<br />

Source: Own compilation, inspired by Wallace (2000:73-5)<br />

Figure 1.3 European Policy-Making Interpreted as Multi-Location Politics<br />

Pan-European &<br />

International Organizations:<br />

OECD/ECMT, UNECE, etc.<br />

EU<br />

- DG Transport<br />

- DG Enlargement<br />

- DG Regional Policy<br />

- DG Environment<br />

Cities<br />

Regions<br />

Countries<br />

Other<br />

Stakeholders:<br />

IFIs, NGOs, etc.<br />

Source: Own compilation, inspired by Wallace (2000:73-5)


18<br />

1.6 Personal Motivations for Choosing the Area of Inquiry<br />

Not only are there many different ways to organize a case study, there are also<br />

many different reasons for doing it. In my case, the formulation of the below described<br />

research questions and propositions evolved and developed out of the professional work I<br />

had been doing for an international non-governmental organization in New York 8 which<br />

provides technical assistance to environmental groups in Central Europe in the area of<br />

sustainable transport advocacy. Of course, as is also documented in this study, most<br />

environmental NGOs have a particular normative view of what “sustainability” means in<br />

the area of transport, and this view is neither fully congruent with interpretations<br />

presented by the European Union nor with that of the business community. The goal of<br />

my thesis, however, is less a verification or a falsification of one particular view on the<br />

environment and on sustainability than an exploratory analysis of the “contextual<br />

discourses” arising from the issue of EU transport sector investment decision-making in<br />

the particular context of enlargement. The thesis thus provided me with a welcome<br />

opportunity to “step back” from an area of work that I had become politically involved in<br />

and to look at it from a more detached, more de-politicized perspective. In particular, I<br />

wanted to re-visit some questions for which the environmental movement often has alltoo-easy<br />

and limited answers. Attacking decision-makers for their lack of action<br />

whenever a particular Habitats or Birds Directive is not recognized by investors, for<br />

example, is useful in that it applies pressure where it is most effective politically, e.g. at<br />

the level of legally sanctioned environmental agendas. What is missing from such a<br />

8 The name of the NGO is the Institute for Transportation and Development Policy (ITDP). See www.ITDP.org.


19<br />

perspective, however, is the question in how far a legislative approach to environmental<br />

matters even really addresses the crux of the “sustainability problem”.<br />

Since environmental advocates fight for particular political outcomes, their world<br />

of environmental politics appears neatly divided into allies, potential allies and<br />

adversaries. Of course, this distinction does not entirely dissolve itself once one takes up<br />

the role of social science researcher. My research is quite obviously motivated by an<br />

ongoing belief that sustainability issues are in fact important in transport decision-making<br />

and that planners and policy-makers can produce socially and environmentally preferable<br />

outcomes by better operationalizing and implementing this admittedly still fuzzy concept.<br />

This is the background before which I embark upon my scholarly review of currently<br />

dominant EU discourses of sustainability. In my view, to not ground one’s research<br />

within a larger belief system of human action is careless social science. The key issue,<br />

however, is not whether or not one’s choice of a particular topic is personally motivated,<br />

but whether the resulting research is carried out in a logical, plausible, transparent and<br />

responsible manner. Motivated science does not automatically mean biased science. The<br />

two are often confused.<br />

Yin (1994:56) lists five key skills a good case study investigator needs to posses:<br />

she needs to “be able to ask good questions,” “be a good listener,” “be adaptive and<br />

flexible,” “have a firm grasp of the issues being studied [in order to] focus the relevant<br />

events and information to be sought to manageable proportions,” and “be unbiased by<br />

preconceived notions, including those derived from theory.” Certainly, the last two items<br />

do not always go hand in hand very easily, since the more one already knows about a<br />

particular issue, the more likely one also has opinions about it. Yin’s key criterion for


20<br />

qualifying as “unbiased” is that a person “be sensitive and responsive to contradictory<br />

evidence” (p.56). In my case, my entire research design, and its theory-building part in<br />

particular, should in fact be looked at as a sensitive response - if not so much to the<br />

contradictions then definitely to the limits that (too strongly) environmentally biased<br />

views on European Union transport infrastructure decision-making pose for scholarly<br />

inquiry. (This is of course also true for fields other than transportation). In the end, I am<br />

convinced that my extensive prior knowledge of the subject area enriched rather than<br />

limited my case study accounts, and that it even helped me to overcome the frustrations<br />

of working in a field where contradictory evidence and biased research is particularly<br />

extensive. Few areas of inquiry seem to be as inconclusive and contradictory in their<br />

evidence as that of “sustainable” transport infrastructure investment.<br />

1.7 Initial Considerations: “Rhetoric versus Reality” or “Realrationalität”?<br />

The starting point of this study was the realization, made during my NGO work,<br />

that there seemed to be a stark contrast between the sustainability objectives expressed in<br />

key EU documents (e.g. the EC and EU Treaties, the EU Common Transport Policy, the<br />

EU Sustainable Development Strategy, the EU Spatial Development Perspective etc.) and<br />

actual EU-led transport-sector infrastructure investments, both in the member states<br />

themselves and in the central European EU-accession countries. Take the issue of modal<br />

preferences, for example. Even according to very mainstream sources, sustainable<br />

transport development implies an increase of investments in the environmentally friendly<br />

modes of rail, public transit, and combined transport and a move away from car and truck<br />

dominance (ECMT and OECD 1990; ECMT 1995b; World Bank 1996). As will be


21<br />

shown and further discussed in this study, neither within the EU nor in EU accession<br />

countries is there a clearly recognizable trend in this direction. Inside the EU, the two<br />

most important EU funds allocating money for transport infrastructure are the European<br />

Regional Development Fund (ERDF) and the Cohesion Fund. From 1994-1999, over<br />

70% of the € 13.7 billion of EDRF Objective 1 funding went to roads. 9 The imbalance<br />

was equally pronounced in the case of the EU Cohesion Fund which provides special<br />

grant funding to the four poorest EU member states (Greece, Ireland, Portugal and<br />

Spain). From 1993 to 1999, priority transport investments for Trans-European Network<br />

projects in the four Cohesion countries accounted for over € 5 billion, of which 69% went<br />

to roads. The situation is likely to be similar for EU investments into the transport<br />

infrastructure systems in future member states. According to the EU-initiated Transport<br />

Infrastructure Needs Assessment for the CEE candidate countries (TINA), road sector<br />

investments were estimated to account for less than half of all funds needed in both<br />

Poland and Hungary, while the rail sector should receive at least 40% of all funds.<br />

Nevertheless, until the year 2000, both European Union grant programs and loans<br />

approved by the “house bank” of the European Union, the European Investment Bank<br />

(EIB), had allocated less than 30% of their funds to the rail sector. The most important<br />

EU grant program for the CEE candidate countries, the so-called Phare program,<br />

allocated 53% percent of the total € 884.2 million disbursed until 1999 to road, while<br />

only 32% went to rail. This observable discrepancy between the rhetoric and the reality<br />

of investments motivated me to attempt an investigation into the most important<br />

institutional, economic, (geo)political or other relevant factors that influence European<br />

9 Objective 1 funding is designated for the least developed regions of the EU, i.e. regions where GDP per<br />

capita is below 75% of the EU average.


22<br />

Union transport decision-making, both inside the EU and in future candidate countries. 10<br />

Why does the EU not “put its money where its mouth is,” to put it colloquially?<br />

Generally speaking, there are two possible explanations: either the EU does not<br />

want to implement its own sustainability agenda - which raises fundamental questions<br />

about the EU the “true” motives of EU decision-making, i.e. its rationality - or the EU is<br />

not able to implement its own sustainability agenda - which raises fundamental questions<br />

about the EU’s function as a modern planning and policy-making body, i.e. its power and<br />

legitimation. Note that such an (in)ability to “implement sustainability” in turn has<br />

several dimensions: First, there is the issue of “democratic legitimation” in the narrower<br />

sense, i.e. the fact that within the currently prevailing context of multi-level, democratic<br />

governance in Europe, the EU’s decision-making powers are limited by issues of national<br />

sovereignty and subsidarity. Second, there is a procedural dimension focusing on the setup<br />

and the (in)efficiency of those institutions actually implementing environmental and<br />

transport policies. Finally, there is a more structural dimension concerning the<br />

fundamental incompatibility of “sustainability” ideals with competing development<br />

goals, e.g. enlargement (“goal incompatibility”). As subsequent sections will show, all<br />

three dimensions provide partial explanations as to why the EU is fundamentally<br />

“incapable” of implementing sustainability.<br />

Taken together, the “rationality” and the “power/legitimation” explanations have<br />

important implications with regard to the institutional nature of the European Union and<br />

to the problem of (sustainable) planning and policy-making at the Pan-European, supranational<br />

level. Let us briefly consider two possible explanatory paths:<br />

10 To be sure, both the “rhetoric” and the “reality” of EU investments are elaborated in much more detail in<br />

the following pages. For a closer analysis of EU policy statements on sustainable transport, see Part II. For


23<br />

On one hand, there is the question of the validity of the approach of “sustainable<br />

transport” and the underlying reasons and rationales for decision-making. One cannot<br />

assert that the EU “fails” to implement its own sustainability agenda without first taking a<br />

closer look at both general and EU specific interpretations of “sustainability” and<br />

“sustainable transport.” We will therefore have to address questions such as: How are the<br />

terms defined? What are their major connotations? How are the concepts<br />

operationalized? What is the relationship between transport and development? How do<br />

the EU's definitions relate to larger discussions around economic development and<br />

environmentalism? Are the presented definitions and arguments coherent and internally<br />

consistent? Can we distinguish different discourses with regard to sustainability and<br />

sustainable transport? The overall aim here is to present an analysis of sustainable<br />

development and sustainable transport as social constructs.<br />

On the other hand, there is the question of the EU’s ability to implement a given<br />

approach. Such a path of analysis asks fundamental questions about the process of<br />

decision-making. Here the focus would be on an institutional analysis of the major<br />

players and the relationships between them, guided by questions such as: Given its own<br />

understanding of the concepts of sustainability as presented in official policy documents,<br />

why do EU decision-makers fail to integrate environmental considerations into transport<br />

investment decisions in the EU? Who are the major decision-makers in transport<br />

planning and policy-making in the EU, especially with regard to Pan-European policies<br />

and projects? Who else is participating in the decision-making process, who is left out?<br />

What is the relationship between those who formulate policy objectives and those who<br />

implement concrete investment projects? Are the formulated goals and objectives<br />

more details on mode-specific EU-led transport infrastructure investments see Part III.


24<br />

consistent with the needs assessed at the local level? And finally: What is the particular<br />

situation in the case of the enlargement countries that are not yet members of the EU?<br />

What are the power relationships between the EU, member states and candidate<br />

countries?<br />

Both explanatory paths are valid ways of organizing an investigative study on EU<br />

transport sector investments, and as we will see, both yield interesting answers about how<br />

the EU makes and implements decisions, not only in the realm of transport, but also as an<br />

institution more generally. However, my study explicitly does not choose between either<br />

path of investigation. Instead, I am interested in showing the relationship between the<br />

validation and the implementation of the concept of sustainable transport. At the<br />

intersection between underlying rationales and real-life processes of decision-making<br />

always lies the intellectual process of rationalization, or, as Bent Flyvbjerg terms it more<br />

appropriately, Realrationalität. For Flyvbjerg (1998:7), “the main question is not only<br />

the Weberian ‘Who governs’ posed by most other students of power-as-entity […] [but]<br />

also the Nietzschean question, ‘What “governmental rationalities” are at work when those<br />

who govern govern?’” Enveloped in an in-depth case study of politics, administration<br />

and planning in the Danish town of Aalborg, Flyvbjerg’s study Rationality and Power<br />

presents a captivating analysis of real-life decision-making in modern (Western)<br />

democracies. The key conclusion of his book is immensely relevant to my own study as<br />

well (Flyvbjerg 1998:236):<br />

The focus of modernity and modern democracy has always been on ‘what should be<br />

done,’ on normative rationality. What I suggest is a reorientation toward the first half<br />

of Machiavelli’s dictum, ‘what is to be done,’ toward verita effecttuale. We need to<br />

rethink and recast the projects of modernity and democracy, and of modern politics,<br />

administration, and planning, in terms of not only rationality but of rationality and<br />

power, Realrationalität. Instead of thinking of modernity and democracy as rational


25<br />

means for dissolving power, we need to see them as practical attempts at regulating<br />

power and domination. When we do this we obtain a better grasp of what modernity<br />

and democracy are in practice and what it takes to change them for the better.<br />

Note that this process is particularly complex in the case of the EU, since all<br />

decision-making is embedded in an overall framework of multi-level governance,<br />

involving a complicated and shifting web of power relationships.<br />

1.8 From a Set of General Research Questions to Six Key Propositions<br />

So in focusing on both, the validity of the sustainable transport ideal and the<br />

difficulties in implementing it, the study brings together the two major paths of analysis<br />

described above. As already evident from above discussions, my study was motivated by<br />

one overarching, dual research question:<br />

Who and what “governs” EU transport infrastructure decision-making, and how is this<br />

decision-making power being rationalized?<br />

The research questions that guided the actual case study review can be summarized as<br />

follows:<br />

?? How can we explain the discrepancies between the sustainability objectives expressed<br />

in key EU Commission policy documents and the reality of EU-led transport sector<br />

infrastructure investments?<br />

?? What are the key defining concepts and justifications used for EU-led transport<br />

infrastructure investments?<br />

?? How are these adapted and/or modified in the case of EU transport infrastructure<br />

investments in the Central European candidate countries?<br />

?? Who are the most influential decision-makers in Pan-European transport policy and<br />

why?


26<br />

I structured the resulting inquiry around six different propositions on EU transport<br />

sector decision-making. These will be approached in consecutive order throughout the<br />

study. The following discussion of these six consecutive propositions therefore also<br />

serves as an overview of the overall structure of this dissertation.<br />

1.8.1 The Ill-Defined Concept Proposition<br />

1) The EU does not implement ‘a sustainable transport agenda’ because it is a flawed<br />

concept that is internally contradictory<br />

In the first theory-building chapter of Part I of this study (Chapter 2), I present<br />

different international definitions for sustainability and sustainable transport. Sustainable<br />

development is typically presented as having three dimensions, namely ‘growth,’<br />

‘equity,’ and ‘environment’. I show that these different connotations connected to the<br />

terms sustainability and sustainable transport are indeed contradictory, i.e. not congruent<br />

with each other. I also discuss the complex and disputed relationship between transport<br />

and economic development in general. Note that the Ill-Defined Concept Proposition<br />

precludes the option of taking a normative approach of simply “picking” one particular<br />

set of sustainability definitions as the “correct” ones. Instead, I pursue my investigation<br />

through the following key proposition:<br />

1.8.2 The Dominant Discourse Proposition<br />

2) The EU employs a discourse in which the concept of ‘sustainable transport’ is<br />

distorted to favor growth objectives at the expense of equity and environmental<br />

preservation. More precisely, EU transport sector decision-making is dominated by the<br />

discursive framework of ecological modernization.


27<br />

Using Maarten Hajer’s (1995) important considerations on the constitutive role of<br />

discourse in policy processes as a starting point, I show that the EU’s framing of<br />

sustainable transport is not neutral but involves important choices with regard to which<br />

objectives are favored.<br />

The pertaining sections analyze sustainability and sustainable<br />

transport as discourse. The two final theory-building chapters of Part I (i.e. Chapter 3<br />

and Chapter 4) set the stage for this core proposition by first defining the notion of<br />

“discursive frameworks” and by then identifying five alternative discursive frameworks<br />

for sustainable transport. Apart from “ecological modernization,” I distinguish the<br />

following four additional alternative discursive frameworks: “reflexive modernization,”<br />

“communicative rationality,” “political economy” and “renunciation.”<br />

In the first<br />

chapter of the “Rhetoric” Part (i.e. Chapter 5 in Part II), I am then able to analyze key EU<br />

documents to show in how far EU discourses are dominated by eco-modernist (i.e.<br />

ecological modernization) ideals.<br />

Since the key aim of my study is not simply to show how flawed and/or biased the<br />

rhetoric of sustainability is, but to also explain actual policy and investment outcomes,<br />

my attention then increasingly turns to the problem of implementing sustainability ideals.<br />

No matter whether it be growth- or ecology-oriented, any chosen sustainability strategy<br />

could still be transformed into an internally consistent, logical set of policy proposals<br />

advocating a particular set of transport investments. What we have, however, is a world<br />

of competing belief systems even within the EU itself. In the end, we encounter not only<br />

different underlying rationales for sustainability, but also for development more<br />

generally. Until this point, I have concentrated on showing the different ways in which<br />

sustainability and sustainable transport have been (re-)interpreted by scholars and


28<br />

decision-makers. But when focusing on the operationalization of the concept of<br />

sustainability within EU decision-making, and its operationalization into actual<br />

guidelines for transport investment decisions in particular, we also have to consider<br />

alternative concepts that might be competing with it. So the second key insight guiding<br />

my discussion of EU “rhetoric” in Part II is that sustainability is but one of several<br />

overarching EU development goals, and that implementation-oriented discourses also aim<br />

at achieving goals other than sustainability. I therefore make the following, additional<br />

proposition with regard to transport-related EU decision-making:<br />

1.8.3 The Conflicting Storylines Proposition<br />

3) Decision-making for Pan-European transport infrastructure investments lacks<br />

consistence and sustainability due to the existence of several, partially complementary,<br />

but also partially competing EU development objectives. These objectives are in turn<br />

expressed through several, partially conflicting guiding visions (‘Leitbilder’) and<br />

storylines.<br />

This key proposition already increasingly shifts our attention away from policy<br />

discourses (“rhetoric”) towards actual investment rationales (“reality”). In Chapter 6, I<br />

use the German notion of Leitbilder to identify and summarize the three overarching EU<br />

“guiding visions” of integration, enlargement and sustainability. I subsequently adapt<br />

Maarten Hajer’s concept of storylines to distinguish four spatial storylines for EU<br />

transport infrastructure investments: “cohesion,” “polycentricity,” “missing links,” and<br />

“bottlenecks.”<br />

Armed with these insights into overall discourses of EU transport-related policies<br />

and programs, I then finally enter the “realities” part of the study. Here, while conscious<br />

of the fact that the two are intimately intertwined (through the concept of


29<br />

Realrationalität), I still need to account for the circumstance that the analytical focus now<br />

increasingly lies on actual decision-making powers, in addition to the above discussed<br />

discursive rationalities. Hence, I make the following additional propositions with regard<br />

to the particular problems of EU decision-making related to transport infrastructure plans<br />

and investments in the context of enlargement:<br />

1.8.4 The Decisional Power Proposition<br />

4) Trans-European Transport Network policies and plans are primarily designed to<br />

satisfy national economic and multi-national corporate interests.<br />

This proposition is related to the Dominant-Discourse Proposition inasmuch as<br />

favoring growth objectives already puts certain interest groups at an advantage over<br />

others. However, the Decisional-Power Proposition goes even further by explicitly<br />

connecting the key issues of discourse, decision-making and policy outcomes. The<br />

pertaining analyses in Chapters 7, 8 and 9 are further guided by two additional<br />

propositions:<br />

1.8.5 The Challenges of Multi-Location Politics Proposition<br />

5) The EU Commission has limited power to formulate and implement its transport sector<br />

objectives and policies, especially with regard to policy concerning the candidate<br />

countries.<br />

This proposition naturally has two dimensions. On one hand, there are the<br />

internal problems of EU governance related to multi-level, or rather: multi-location<br />

decision-making (making it even possible to question concept of multi-level governance<br />

as such). On the other hand, there is the special problem of influencing decision-making<br />

in the candidate countries, focusing on the power-play between the EU and the respective<br />

case study countries (Hungary and Poland). At first sight, one might suspect that the


30<br />

influence of the EU in the candidate countries is even greater than in its member states,<br />

since the candidate countries should be eager to fulfill all necessary requirements for<br />

future membership. However, as we will see, national politics also strongly influence<br />

transport decision-making in the candidate countries, especially when it comes to<br />

strategic and geo-politically important routes and/or large-scale investments.<br />

Taken together, the Decisional-Power and the Multi-Locational Politics<br />

Propositions are particularly helpful for understanding the dynamics of the sub-case<br />

studies presented in Chapters 7 and 8. Chapter 7 focuses on the gestation and<br />

formulation of the EU’s Pan-European Transport Network plans and programs, focusing<br />

on revealing the underlying rationales, key decision makers, and outcomes of the socalled<br />

Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment (TINA) exercise for the Central<br />

Eastern European candidate countries. Chapter 8 presents a review of the first two years<br />

of transport-related funding for Poland and Hungary under the EU’s new Instrument for<br />

Structural Pre-Accession (ISPA).<br />

Finally, I introduce one last proposition which explicitly accounts for the fact that,<br />

once they are fully implemented, EU transport infrastructure decisions of course also<br />

have an impact on transport and land-use patterns at the local/regional level. So<br />

depending on the details of the related planning and implementation processes and the<br />

observable spatial consequences of the respective infrastructures, EU transport-sector<br />

decision-making can thus be interpreted as being more or less “sustainable”. Note that<br />

such value judgments about the local and regional sustainability effects of EU-funded<br />

infrastructures should of course be based on the EU’s own definitions of transport and


31<br />

land-use sustainability, i.e. compare local “realities” with official EU “rhetoric.” The<br />

pertaining proposition has wide-ranging implications:<br />

1.8.6 The Local Impacts Proposition<br />

6) The eco-modernist transport investment decision-making rationales currently<br />

privileged by the EU tend to underestimate the negative local impacts of large-scale<br />

infrastructures. Meanwhile, each of the four alternative discursive frameworks of<br />

”reflexive modernization”, “communicative rationality”, “political economy”, and<br />

“renunciation” adds an important additional dimension to the decision-making process<br />

that would partially rectify this bias.<br />

This final proposition pays homage to the fact that in the transport sector, the<br />

local dimension presents important additional challenges to the analysis of sustainability.<br />

In Chapter 9, I apply the five alternative discursive frameworks for sustainable transport<br />

identified earlier in the study to the concrete case of the EU-funded M0 ring road around<br />

Budapest. I compare how the overarching rationales and resulting policy proposals of<br />

these discursive frameworks are reflected in the local controversies over a large-scale<br />

transport infrastructure. As we will see, not all of the concerns raised within the<br />

alternative discursive frameworks can be easily addressed within currently existing<br />

decision-making structures.<br />

1.8.7 Summarizing the Organization of the Study<br />

It should be noted that the applicability of the different propositions is not as<br />

limited to the various chapters of the study than the above structure might suggest. Also,<br />

individual case studies may serve to illustrate more than one proposition. For example,<br />

the material presented in Chapter 7 tracing the evolution of Pan-European transport<br />

corridors not only provides insights about decisional power dynamics, but it also reflects


32<br />

on multi-location politicking and/or the likely longer-term sustainability impacts of the<br />

favored investment programs. Still, as evident from above outline, I decided to arrange<br />

the findings and insights gathered from the interviews and document materials in a<br />

manner such that the suite of chapters roughly corresponds to the systematic formulation<br />

of the propositions. Table 1.2 summarizes the relationship between the consecutive<br />

introduction of the six propositions and overall structure of the study.<br />

A concluding chapter (Chapter 10) summarizes the various findings of the study.<br />

My general case study conclusions are centered around the formulation of what I term the<br />

“contextual discourse” dilemma of modern capitalist democracies. This dilemma can be<br />

briefly summarized as follows: On one hand, it is true that successful planning and<br />

policy-making is dependent on developing universally applicable, integrative guiding<br />

visions and storylines such as “sustainability” or “cohesion” to guide and legitimize<br />

decision-making. On the other hand, it is also true that such discursive concepts only<br />

become useful policy tools for decision-makers if they can be operationalized into<br />

concrete local/regional agendas resulting in specific investment choices in particular<br />

locales. However, the more grounded planning and policy-making discourses become in<br />

concrete local-regional contexts, the less universally applicable and the more conflictual<br />

and contradictory they become (for additional details see Box 10.1 and subsequent<br />

sections in Chapter 10).


33<br />

Table 1.2 How the Six Propositions Relate to the Overall Structure of the Study<br />

Ch 1 “EU Transport Infrastructure Investment in the Context of Eastern Enlargement”<br />

(Intro)<br />

PART I: THEORY-BUILDING<br />

Ch 2 Defining Sustainability /<br />

Ill-Defined Concept<br />

Sustainable Transport<br />

Ch 3<br />

The Notion of<br />

Discursive Frameworks<br />

Dominant Discourse<br />

Ch 4 Ecological Modernization &<br />

Its Alternatives<br />

PART II: RHETORIC<br />

Ch 5<br />

EU Discourses<br />

Dominant Discourse cont.<br />

(Review of Key Documents)<br />

Ch 6<br />

Four EU Storylines<br />

Conflicting Storylines<br />

for Transport Investments<br />

PART III : REALITIES<br />

Ch 7 Pan-European Corridors /<br />

CEE TINA Network<br />

Ch 8<br />

Ch 9<br />

Ch10<br />

Decisional Power &<br />

Challenges of<br />

Multi-Location Politics<br />

EU transport funds for<br />

Poland & Hungary under ISPA<br />

TINA-node Case Study<br />

Local Impacts<br />

(M0 ring road in Budapest)<br />

PART IV: CONCLUSIONS<br />

Conclusions: The “Contextual Discourse” Dilemma of Planning & Policy<br />

Making<br />

Source: Own complilation<br />

1.9 Methods and Data Sources Used<br />

In order to adequately discuss the various propositions, I employ a mix of several<br />

social science methods. The first, theory-building part of the study (Part I) sets the stage<br />

for the ensuring sections by introducing the study’s overall social constructivist,<br />

discourse-analytical approach and by distinguishing five discursive frameworks for<br />

decision and policy-making. The following “rhetoric” section (Part II) then aims at<br />

understanding the EU from a more EU-centric, Brussels perspective, while the “realities”<br />

sections (Part III) test the developed concepts and ideas “in the field,” i.e. as they relate to<br />

EU transport activities in Poland and Hungary. The above presented research questions


34<br />

and related propositions form the overall framework for the study, helping me to<br />

operationalize each individual step.<br />

In Parts I and II of this study, I rely on a vast array of secondary literature from<br />

many social science sub-fields such as social/urban/planning theory, sociology, political<br />

science, transport planning and policy, regional science, environmental studies or<br />

political economy to formulate and corroborate my various propositions. I also do a<br />

significant amount of direct document analysis. Primary data material is provided by EU<br />

policy documents (both official and unofficial), supplemented with various non-EU<br />

policy papers, as well as informal statements and interviews gathered from various<br />

stakeholders. Part II strongly relies on the social constructivist method of discourse<br />

analysis. In particular, I use the German concept of Leitbilder and on Maarten Hajer’s<br />

concept of storylines to tease out the EU’s conflicting visions with regard to transport<br />

infrastructure investments.<br />

Set against this backdrop, Part III presents the case study on EU transport<br />

infrastructure decision-making in Poland and Hungary. Here, I primarily use information<br />

gathered from documents, personal interviews, and during conferences and workshops<br />

related to the event. For the preparation of the case study chapter on the Budapest ring<br />

road I also heavily rely on interviews and informal document material, especially for the<br />

reconstruction of the debate between the European Investment Bank and<br />

environmentalists. Personal visits to various ring road sites were made during my<br />

interview phase in August 2000 and again in January 2001.


35<br />

1.9.1 Document Review<br />

Especially the second part of the study heavily relies on extensive review of<br />

policy documents, primarily but not exclusively from the European Commission. The<br />

availability of EU and EU-special agency documents and publications is very mixed.<br />

Most official, and an increasing number of unofficial EU documents are available<br />

through the Office for Official Publications of the European Commission (OOPEC).<br />

More importantly, an increasing number of official and unofficial EU Council,<br />

Parliament and Directorate General papers, policies, decisions and communications are<br />

available on the sprawling (and sometimes difficult to navigate) EU web site<br />

(www.europa.eu.int).<br />

In addition to this, there exists a large body of hard-to-track-down, more specific<br />

“gray” research literature, often funded and/or carried out by the European Union. Much<br />

is in the form of commissioned but not very widely published studies and reports. 11<br />

Many of the more politically “dangerous” consultant reports on large-scale transport<br />

project assessments are not easily accessible to normal academic researchers, and many<br />

internal assessments at international financial institutions such as the European<br />

Investment Bank (EIB) are even confidential. At the time when I was doing my field<br />

research, even the ISPA (Instruments for Structural Policies for Pre-Accession) National<br />

Strategy documents in Poland and Hungary were not all publicly available and had to be<br />

obtained though insider channels. Ironically, this lack of transparency, limit on<br />

11 To give a specific example: when a colleague of mine conducted interviews with European Union<br />

officials on the issue of strategic environmental assessments (SEAs) for transport projects she asked several<br />

interview partners for literature. She returned with no less than ten photocopied cover pages of reports on<br />

this specific topic alone, all of them EU-funded or initiated studies carried out within the last five years.<br />

None of these were easily available through official channels, nor were they listed in library search engines.


36<br />

information, and evasion of public accountability forms part of the story my research<br />

intends to tell.<br />

1.9.2 Interviews<br />

The list of potential interviewees developed naturally out of the initial process of<br />

identifying the relevant stakeholders.<br />

Most key institutions, organizations and<br />

individuals in European transport infrastructure decision-making are listed in the<br />

glossary. Many of my choices for interviews at the European Union were selfexplanatory<br />

in the sense that they could be picked directly from the organigram of the<br />

relevant EU bureaucracies. After an initial set of interviews, a reputational (“snowball”)<br />

method was used to identify the most relevant future interview partners, i.e. past<br />

interviewees were asked to provide names of other persons that they thought were<br />

particularly knowledgeable in the suggested areas of inquiry. In the end, the ultimate<br />

selection of interviewees was purposive in the sense that I relied on my own good<br />

judgment to define the final list of interview partners. However, it should also be noted<br />

that my own long-standing professional experience in the area of sustainable transport<br />

advocacy provided me with substantial advance knowledge of the key players.<br />

All interviews, including all the longer, specifically arranged talks at the EU in<br />

Brussels, and at various ministries and offices in Warsaw and Budapest, were conducted<br />

as open-ended, unstructured interviews. I always had a set of more general policy<br />

questions as well as some specific informational questions for the interviewees, but there<br />

was no fixed list of questions. This was largely due to the complexity of the issues<br />

involved and due to the fact that different interview partners provided information about


37<br />

very different areas of the overall case study. Triangulation was nevertheless aimed for<br />

whenever possible, i.e. different interview partners were asked the same question when<br />

they were working in the same general area. For example, desk officers at the ISPA Unit<br />

in Brussels were asked similar questions about the successes and failures of the first<br />

round of applications received and on the formulation of the ISPA strategy document.<br />

Information was considered to be true when confirmed by several interview partners.<br />

Since I guaranteed anonymity to the persons interviewed, they are usually not quoted by<br />

name. A large number of additional talks were also conducted in more informal settings,<br />

outside office surroundings over lunch or dinner. Sometimes meetings were also<br />

conducted in a quasi-participant-observation manner, for example during the course of<br />

the many workshops and conferences related to European transport in which I took part<br />

over the course of the last four years, and where I was often not only a passive observer<br />

but also an active participant. Annex II provides a detailed list of the most important<br />

contacts met over the course of the research period, while Annex III provides additional<br />

information on the relevant meetings, conferences, and seminars I attended during that<br />

time.<br />

1.9.3 General Statistical Data<br />

The EU Statistical Office collects up to date information on economic, social and<br />

environmental indicators. OECD statistics are also generally up to date and helpful for<br />

comparative purposes. Quantitative data is used primarily to establish measures for the<br />

“sustainability” of existing transport systems and projections about future developments.<br />

Readily available data includes information on motorization rates, transport-related air<br />

pollution in major urbanized areas, rail and road network density and intensity of use,


38<br />

maintenance and construction costs, national and regional level transport investments by<br />

mode, percentage of transport sector investment by international financial institutions etc.<br />

Since there is no European-wide traffic demand model, most traffic projections,<br />

especially when it comes to Pan-European East-West connections are highly unreliable<br />

and are therefore only discussed within the political context that they are used.


39<br />

Printed on September 21, 2002<br />

Last revised on Sept 15, 2002<br />

PART I: THEORY-BUILDING<br />

Five Discursive Frameworks for a<br />

“Sustainable Europe”


40<br />

Printed on October 31, 2002<br />

Last revised on Sept 15, 2002<br />

CHAPTER 2<br />

Transport, Development and Sustainability:<br />

First Approximations<br />

2.1 Introduction....................................................................................................... 41<br />

2.2 Transport and Economic Development ............................................................ 41<br />

2.2.1 From Henry Ford’s Assembly Lines to VW’s “Transparent Factory” ..... 42<br />

2.2.2 Macroeconomic aspects of transport investments .................................... 46<br />

2.2.3 Reduction of transport cost ....................................................................... 46<br />

2.2.4 Inter-regional trade theory ........................................................................ 47<br />

2.2.5 Production Function studies: “Is public expenditure productive?” .......... 48<br />

2.2.6 Rethinking the theory on transport investments ....................................... 51<br />

2.3 “Sustainable Development”.............................................................................. 57<br />

2.4 “Sustainable Transport”.................................................................................... 66<br />

2.5 Two Ill-Defined Concepts?............................................................................... 72


41<br />

2.1 Introduction<br />

Neither development nor sustainability are easily definable concepts. Various,<br />

internationally sanctioned, normative definitions of sustainable development and of<br />

sustainable transport exist. Most famously among them are the Brundlandt definition of<br />

sustainable development and the Vancouver principles for sustainable transport, both of<br />

which are presented below. However, none of these normative definitions are directly<br />

translatable into concrete infrastructure investment proposals at the local level. More<br />

importantly, even these internationally accepted definitions are contestable, depending on<br />

one’s underlying belief systems and rationales. The aim of this present chapter is simply<br />

to present a series of first approximations regarding the notions of economic development<br />

and sustainability in relation to the transport sector. My initial proposition in<br />

approaching the subject is that the notion of “sustainable transport development” really<br />

remains a relatively ill-defined concept. Later chapters will set this “Ill-Defined<br />

Concept” proposition within a larger context of sustainability and sustainable transport as<br />

contested discourses.<br />

2.2 Transport and Economic Development<br />

Transport has long been considered central to urban and regional development,<br />

and to the concept of economic growth in general. The establishment of trade routes is<br />

an essential prerequisite for the expansion of market ranges. And as settlements grow, an<br />

efficient internal organization of infrastructures is key to facilitating the efficient<br />

movements of people and goods. Distance and density remain the two most fundamental<br />

concepts in spatial development. But today’s cities and regions are vastly different from<br />

the places we used to live in as little as fifty years ago. As the next section shows, the


42<br />

relationship between transport, transport infrastructures and economic development has<br />

been dramatically redefined over the last half century.<br />

2.2.1 From Henry Ford’s Assembly Lines to VW’s “Transparent Factory” 1<br />

Wealth creation as a whole has become an increasingly complex and dematerialized<br />

concept. Successful modern economies are less and less based on heavy<br />

production industries dependent on large-scale flows of material goods and bulk<br />

production. Instead, they rely on complex webs of inter-dependent service sector<br />

industries that are much more dependent on flexible, small batch production and just-intime<br />

delivery. Technological innovations have also vastly expanded the range of<br />

transport options, with traditional land-based modes of transportation such as road and<br />

rail now intensely competing both among themselves and with water and air transport.<br />

Regardless of particular emphases and specialized terminologies, there is<br />

widespread agreement that Western industrial societies now operate under a so-called<br />

post-Fordist mode(l) of development. Since the mid-seventies, production in the<br />

advanced Western societies has switched from mass production/mass consumption to<br />

more flexible, just-in-time delivery of less standardized, more differentiated products.<br />

Volkswagen’s recently opened transparent luxury car manufacture in Dresden, Germany<br />

1 Advertised by Volkswagen (VW) as “the world’s most fascinating automotive assembly plant” and<br />

opened in March 2002 with much national fanfare, the new VW car factory in Dresden, Germany<br />

symbolizes the quintessential post-Fordist (and, in many ways, post-modern) production space. The plant’s<br />

name “Gläserne Manufaktur,” – which VW itself translates as “Transparent Factory,” but which might be<br />

more archaically translated as “Vitreous Manufactory” and whose German name also contains a clear<br />

reference to the world-famous Dresden Porcelain Manufactory (Porzellan-Manufaktur) – is to be taken<br />

quite literally in the sense that its outside walls are entirely made of glass so that all production processes<br />

can be in full view of spectators. The plant is laid out to custom-produce 150 luxury sedans per day. All<br />

workers wear clean, white overalls. For additional information and images of the plant, check out<br />

http://www.glaeserne-manufaktur.de .


43<br />

is probably the most extreme example for this transformation. New organizational<br />

patterns and social structures have become dependent on expanded service economies<br />

and advanced telecommunications. The overarching theme of decision-making under<br />

post-Fordism is clearly flexibility. Theorists researching these so-called post-Fordist<br />

transformations of course continue to argue about the primary causes and effects of the<br />

transformation (see especially the edited volume by Amin 1994). In the mid-1980s to<br />

1990s, scholars variously emphasized deindustrialization (e.g. Bluestone and Harrison<br />

1982), and the rise of service sector economies (e.g. Häußermann and Siebel 1995),<br />

corporate restructuring (e.g. Harrison 1994), new divisions of labor (e.g. Massey 1984;<br />

Harrison 1988; Sayer and Walker 1992), flexible specialization (Piore and Sabel 1984),<br />

the rise of “new industrial spaces” (Scott 1988) as well as the restructuring of local land<br />

and real estate markets (e.g. Harvey 1985; Krätke 1991). (French) regulation school<br />

scholars particular analyze the new organizational form late Capitalism has taken by<br />

tracing different “accumulation regimes” (Aglietta 1979; Lipietz 1986; Boyer 1990),<br />

more recently also focusing on environmental implications of changes in labor relations,<br />

presenting a political ecology perspective (e.g. Lipietz 1997). Lately, the key Post-<br />

Fordism-related catch phrase is the rise of the Network, or Information Economy (see<br />

especially Castells 1989; Castells 1996; Castells 1997; Castells 1998).<br />

Both the post-Fordist transformation in general and the resulting reconceptualization<br />

of time and space in particular are doubtless important concepts with<br />

many additional dimensions relevant to the present study. For example, Amin and<br />

Tomaney (1995:31) in their volume on the “myth” of EU cohesion, characterize the new<br />

emerging [European] economy as a “learning economy” in which the key competitive


44<br />

elements are knowledge control, information, innovation, the capacity to quickly renew<br />

products, as well as “the capacity to reduce the friction of distance and time” through the<br />

use of informatics, advanced telecommunications and transport systems. Moreover, as<br />

Banister and Berechman (1993:11) point out, in the modern economies of Western and<br />

Central Europe, “industry can now locate almost anywhere as it is not dependent on a<br />

single source of raw material inputs.”<br />

Regarding infrastructure development, the shift towards a post-Fordist,<br />

“networked” industrial model has elevated the importance of high-tech services and<br />

technologies over traditional rail-, road- or water-based transport systems. Investment<br />

into the general infrastructure of regions and cities, such as communication, education,<br />

training, and R&D capabilities is often needed more than investments into traditional<br />

transport systems. With the advent of the Information Age, the lines between social and<br />

economic overhead capital are becoming increasingly blurred. Especially in less favored<br />

regions, successful capitalist restructuring is thought to depend more than anything on<br />

“building local institutional capacity” (Amin and Tomaney 1995:218). Within these<br />

institutional settings, post-Fordist scholars stress the importance of territorially bound<br />

linkages, and predict “an increase in the regional embeddedness of firms and, hence,<br />

benefits even for peripheral regions” (Giunta and Martinelli 1995:246). Note that such an<br />

emphasis on the vertical disintegration of firms and the emergence of new spatial<br />

structures is somewhat at odds with the two-way roads argument (see 2.5.4 “Rethinking<br />

the theory on transport investments”). More importantly, if it were true that the new<br />

capitalism was no longer based on economies of scale, it would give smaller, flexible,<br />

interconnected firms in less central locations better opportunities to compete through


45<br />

economies of scope, regarding transport investments. While somewhat doubtful<br />

empirically, such arguments would then call for a focus on intra-regional rather than<br />

inter-regional infrastructures, and for a redirecting of funds from Pan-European, largescale<br />

infrastructures towards locally-targeted, regional infrastructure investments. 2<br />

Concurrent with these observations, Van Geenhuizen and Ratti (1998:84) identify<br />

four basic forces that are reshaping the geopolitical and socioeconomic positions of<br />

European regions: 1) the unification of Europe (which resulted in an increased openness<br />

of regions), 2) the shift to a new local-global network economy, 3) the (related) rapid<br />

progress in information technology, and 4) policies for an environmentally sustainable<br />

growth (however these might be defined). The first three factors in particular lead to an<br />

increased competition between European regions and cities (Cheshire and Gordon 1995).<br />

Of course not everyone has drawn the same conclusions from the new realities unfolding<br />

around us. While everyone seems to agree that investments into physical rail and road<br />

infrastructures will remain crucially important even in the information age, opinions<br />

about investment priorities differ widely. This following section presents a general<br />

overview over theories on the economic aspects of transport investments.<br />

2 Not all scholars agree that flexible specialization is a necessary outcome, however. Capello and Gillespie<br />

(1993), for example, use a Regulation School underpinning to investigate spatial changes in Europe. They<br />

compare “the long-distance, regular, standardized commodity flow demanded by the (late) Fordist<br />

production system” with several future scenarios, notably Piore and Sabel's classic “flexible specialization”<br />

model of industrial organization and a “network firm/global-local” scenario. Interestingly, Capello and<br />

Gillespie (1993:58) raise doubts over “the over-idealistic view that a completely different industrial and<br />

spatial structure can be developed, with completely opposite features from those of Fordism.” They see the<br />

most likely future scenario in their own global-local model, where so-called network firms aim at<br />

“diversified mass production.” They conclude that “[w]ith respect to spatial organization, the outcome … is<br />

far less dramatic than the one suggested by [Piori’s and Sable’s] ‘flexible specialization’ scenario…. [I]t<br />

can be argued that the spatial extent of firms will remain … largely the same.” 2 The most serious drawback<br />

with Regulation school-type Post-Fordist scholars such as Capello and Gillespie, of course, is their often<br />

surprisingly narrow focus on the changing nature and re-organization of firms. Infrastructure decisions are<br />

then seen as simply following the (new or old) logic of capitalism, without much room for agency in the<br />

decision-making process.


46<br />

2.2.2 Macroeconomic aspects of transport investments<br />

Much confusion persists over the growth potentials of infrastructure investments.<br />

The simplistic notion that cities and regions will necessarily grow stronger with increased<br />

trade and interaction does not carefully enough distinguish between different<br />

beneficiaries, i.e. the economic interests of a) existing businesses in a particular city or<br />

region whose production and service costs will be affected by the improvement of<br />

infrastructures, b) consumers/employees inside the region, c) businesses outside the<br />

region who supply the region with products and services and/or receive products, services<br />

or labor from it (or wish to do so in the future) and d) consumers/laborers outside the<br />

region. All too often, economic growth potential is only assessed in terms of the benefits<br />

accrued by local firms, not residents. It is thus worth considering several macroeconomic<br />

dynamics in more detail.<br />

2.2.3 Reduction of transport cost<br />

Traditionally, the reduction of travel costs has been the most important factor by<br />

which economists calculated the economic benefits of road improvements. In theory,<br />

road investments are supposed to lead to an overall lowering of transport costs, most<br />

notably through the reduction of delivery and access times. Improved transport<br />

conditions increase the market range for producers. However, in mature economies such<br />

as Western Europe and the US, this has rarely proven to be a significant factor in<br />

production patterns (SACTRA1999). Even the European Commission now admits that<br />

transport costs represent less than 5 percent of the total production cost of goods and


47<br />

services in Europe (CEC1999b). Button (1993) also stresses the declining importance of<br />

transport costs and estimates that they now account for as little as 2 to 3 percent of total<br />

costs. For the US context, Boarnet (1997) points out that previous studies often<br />

overestimated the macroeconomic effects of road investments by counting in both the<br />

reduced travel costs for producers and the resulting lower consumer prices, hence in<br />

effect double-counting the benefit. Also, since in post-industrial societies products are<br />

increasingly high-value goods resulting transport cost components are relatively low.<br />

This does not mean that transport infrastructures overall are less important. But the<br />

demand for higher quality, faster infrastructure is more important than a quantitative<br />

improvement of infrastructures per se. It should also be noted that the rise of<br />

telecommunication has not necessarily replaced travel with electronic transactions but in<br />

many instances even created new demand for movement. Even in cases where<br />

production costs are lowered due to a fall in transport costs caused by infrastructure<br />

investment, the output effect depends on whether the fall in costs is passed through to<br />

prices and, if it is, on the price elasticity of demand. Thus market elasticities and<br />

competitive conditions in the transport-using sector are critical determinants of the<br />

outcome.<br />

2.2.4 Inter-regional trade theory<br />

In some cases, poor accessibility may actually benefit and protect businesses in<br />

weaker regions. In these cases, better transport connections open local markets to the<br />

increased competition of larger businesses outside the regions that produce a greater<br />

variety of products at lower prices. In other words, the regional monopoly power of


48<br />

existing businesses is reduced.<br />

This is a key component of the ‘wider economic<br />

benefits’ story. In these cases, local consumers benefit, but the region as a whole may be<br />

negatively affected by the local non-competitive businesses who struggle and begin to<br />

fail. The negative employment effects from failing local businesses may outweigh<br />

consumer benefits from lower prices. Opening the region up to intra-regional<br />

competition therefore requires at least some local sectors to be strong enough to survive<br />

the competition. Given the increasing integration of European economies both within<br />

current member states and with Central Eastern European countries, regional isolation is<br />

of course increasingly a non-option for European regions, but regional economists need<br />

to carefully analyze the particular strengths and weaknesses of the region in question<br />

before transport-investment-led economic development strategies can be successfully<br />

employed. Otherwise, investments might exacerbate existing divergence. As P. Martin<br />

(1999:12) notes, “recent models of geographic economics show that regional integration,<br />

by reducing transaction costs between the regions, may lead to self-sustaining<br />

inequality.”<br />

2.2.5 Production Function studies: “Is public expenditure productive?”<br />

In the late eighties, especially in the US, the discussion over transport<br />

infrastructure benefits shifted away from individual project analysis to studies that sought<br />

to assess the larger relationship between total infrastructure stock in a region and its<br />

economic performance. This production function approach was inspired by the larger<br />

debate spawned by Aschauer’s (1988) provocative public capital hypothesis. His core<br />

argument was that public investments created benefits that spilled over to many areas


49<br />

distant from the actual project. These spillover benefits, it was believed, could be<br />

demonstrated by taking a more network-oriented approach, that looks at how a particular<br />

road (or rail) investment changes accessibility dynamics in other parts of the road (or rail)<br />

network. The argument obviously has large political implications. If a general<br />

relationship between infrastructure investment and economic wealth could be plausibly<br />

demonstrated, then an expanded government role in stimulating investment into public<br />

capital was justified. The narrower neo-classical approaches that focus on cost-benefit<br />

analyses at the project level then could be said to underestimate the economic effects of<br />

public investments.<br />

In the specific context of the US, Aschauer, and others after him, argued that the<br />

downturn in economic productivity in the US in the early 1970s could largely be<br />

explained by the overall decrease in (public) infrastructure investment since the mid-<br />

1960s. Consequently, they argued, only a pro-public investment approach would be able<br />

to bring growth rates in the US back up to previous levels. So the supposed positive<br />

relationship between increases in public infrastructure stock and the productivity of<br />

private sector capital was largely asserted through negative deduction. Aschauer’s<br />

conclusions were immediately contradicted by a number of authors, both on empirical<br />

and more ideological grounds. Interestingly, while several authors arrived at similar<br />

results as Aschauer, Ford and Poret (1991) employed a similar methodology but<br />

expanded their study to include longer data over longer time periods and for several<br />

additional OECD countries, and they end up rejecting the public capital hypothesis.<br />

Other authors have attacked Aschauer on methodological grounds. Aschauer’s focus on<br />

total capital stock, i.e. an exclusive focus on quantitative infrastructure measures, versus


50<br />

the qualitative aspects of the infrastructure in question is especially problematic.<br />

Gramlich (1994) presents an important review essay on the debates. Boarnet’s (1997)<br />

more recent review article on highways and economic productivity also discusses<br />

implications for policy reform in the US context. R. Martin (1999:143ff) discusses<br />

several mid-1990s studies that lend support to Aschauer’s hypothesis for the EU context.<br />

In particular, Seitz and Licht (1995) look at the West German Länder during the 1971 and<br />

1988 period, and Mas et al. (1996) look at Spain. However, the specific emphasis in<br />

these studies is on whether public capital has cost-reducing and productivity-enhancing<br />

effects on the private sector. In other words, their interest is only in whether private firms<br />

benefit, not the resident populations. Wherever these studies find evidence for positive<br />

inter-regional spillover effects from network enhancement, they also find that these<br />

effects decline over time.<br />

In the end, Aschauer, while providing an important ideological boost to proinvestment<br />

professionals and politicians, is not very useful in helping decision-makers<br />

with either the location or even the concrete nature of the investments. Boarnet (1997)<br />

noted: “The most reasonable interpretation of the production function literature is that the<br />

US infrastructure stock is well developed, such that further public capital investment will<br />

have little additional economic impact.” Also, when summarizing recent U.S. literature,<br />

Rephann and Isserman (1994) found that when looking at the economic effects of<br />

highway construction, empirical studies have broken down the causal links into three<br />

different dimensions, looking at effect over time, by industry and by region. They also<br />

insist that study periods need to be divided into construction and post-construction stages,


51<br />

as economic multiplier effects of infrastructures are most evident while construction and<br />

engineering firms employ labor and purchase equipment.<br />

In the end, the biggest problem with the Aschauer debate is that by limiting the<br />

discussion to an aggregate analysis of total investment stock, we learn nothing about<br />

whether, for example, road investments are more ‘productive’ than rail investments or<br />

whether investments are more ‘productive’ in core or peripheral regions. Yet these<br />

questions, as we will see in the ensuing chapters, lie at the heart of EU regional<br />

development policy.<br />

2.2.6 Rethinking the theory on transport investments<br />

State-of-the art regional development theory, including most recent research<br />

funded by the EU itself, now offers a much more careful assessment of the economic<br />

benefits of transport investments than it did ten years ago. This is not only due to the<br />

overall rethinking of regional policy, but also relates to an earlier shift in emphasis from<br />

merely large-scale infrastructure investments to high-quality ones. The EU’s recognition<br />

that the greatest economic benefits were likely to result from closing gaps in<br />

infrastructure connections in (centrally located) border regions rather than from a higher<br />

endowment of infrastructure stock in peripheral regions already indicated a significant<br />

shift in thinking away from a merely quantitative approach to a more qualitative one.<br />

Additionally, recent empirical studies emerging from a variety of EU countries,<br />

particularly from those countries that have received large sums of Cohesion Fund aid for<br />

road construction, provide strong counter-evidence against the notion that large-scale<br />

transport infrastructures are a panacea for economic development. Even early on, some


52<br />

European researchers warned that correlations between transport endowment and<br />

regional wealth were more likely to point to a historical relationship due to long-term<br />

agglomeration processes and did not necessarily reflect recent infrastructure investments<br />

(Brocker and Peschel 1988). A London School of Economics study on the socioeconomic<br />

impacts of transport projects financed by the Cohesion Fund found that the<br />

actual impacts varied widely, even for carefully selected infrastructure investments (LSE<br />

1997). Several recent studies, in particular, cast serious doubt on the notion that weaker<br />

regions always benefit from transport investments (see especially Vickerman,<br />

Spiekermann et al. 1999). Even those scholars who continue to believe that transport<br />

investments are a key trigger for economic benefits increasingly admit that these benefits<br />

will not necessarily be reaped by the majority of inhabitants in the disadvantaged<br />

regions. 3<br />

The Italian Mezzogiorno presents a strong example of a lagging region where a<br />

relatively high endowment with transport infrastructure has not as of yet resulted in a<br />

significant rise of local incomes, thereby strengthening the frequent assertion that other<br />

socio-economic factors are more important (also see CEC 1999b). Meanwhile, the<br />

Nordic countries present the opposite case of highly successful regions with high average<br />

incomes and relatively low-density transport infrastructures. In fact, the Nordic countries<br />

are an interesting reminder that transport is a derived demand and that the key<br />

comparison for inter-regional or international comparisons is infrastructure endowment<br />

per capita, rather than per square mile or kilometer, as other studies have implied.<br />

Comparing the Nordic countries to the EU 15 average, it is obvious that the Nordic<br />

countries have significantly less roads and railways per square kilometer, a fact easily<br />

3 Also see the discussions in Chapter 5.


53<br />

explained by the lower population densities (see figure 2.1). However, both passenger<br />

and freight mileages per year are larger in the Nordic countries, owing to the simple fact<br />

that larger distances must be overcome. Interestingly, the so-called peripheral countries<br />

in the North also have higher GDPs per capita than the EU average. (Note that we will<br />

return to these issues in Chapter 6 during our discussion of the EU storylines of<br />

“cohesion.”)<br />

Figure 2.1 The EU and the Nordic Countries Compared<br />

140<br />

120<br />

100<br />

EU 15<br />

Nordic*<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

* Data<br />

includes<br />

Denmark,<br />

Finland,<br />

Iceland,<br />

Norway,<br />

Sweden<br />

20<br />

0<br />

Population Density<br />

(inh/km2)<br />

Railways (m/km2) Roads (10m/km2) Mileage per<br />

inhabitant<br />

(100km/inh)<br />

Freight Mileage<br />

(100tkm/inh)<br />

GDP<br />

(US$1000/capita)<br />

Data Sources: Nordic Council of Ministers. 1999. "The Northern Dimension and EU<br />

Transport Policy." Stockholm: Nordregio; World Bank Data query (1999 data)


54<br />

In examining the difficult question whether investments in large-scale transport<br />

links bring economic development benefits, both costs and benefits therefore need to be<br />

carefully assessed on a case-by-case basis. Even if an investment comes up positive in<br />

the end, this still only means that from the perspective of the project promoters, the<br />

benefits were greater than the costs. There still might be losses. And depending on the<br />

inclusiveness of the cost-benefit methodologies employed, significant losses may be<br />

externalized. Often economic benefits are reaped at the expense of greater environmental<br />

impacts, such as air pollution, which raise health care expenditures.<br />

Interestingly, the narrowness of cost-benefit approaches has been attacked from a<br />

number of different camps, and often for opposite political reasons. Environmental<br />

externality scholars attack cost-benefit analysis not for the benefits but for the costs that<br />

remain unaccounted for in traditional analyses. In the case of new toll roads, for<br />

example, environmentalists attempting to block investments will point to increasing<br />

traffic congestion and raising pollution on parallel networks due to shifted traffic onto<br />

(toll-free) roads. Meanwhile, investment boosters attempting to leverage additional<br />

highway investments that cannot be justified by narrow project analysis alone will attack<br />

cost-benefit analysis for not counting macro benefits. Rural politicians are still<br />

particularly prone to hold on to the mistaken notion that roads alleviate poverty by<br />

automatically bringing employment and growth. It should also be noted that as long as<br />

the external costs of transport, particularly for freight, remain as highly externalized as in<br />

Europe (see especially Teufel 1989), easier transport access is likely to allow<br />

manufacturers to use production inputs from more and more distant places. The longer<br />

the distances traveled, the larger the environmental impact. The irrationality of using


55<br />

increasingly diverse inputs was underscored by Böge (1995) who demonstrated that if all<br />

product relationships were examined, i.e. if one included all the distances the different<br />

ingredients and packaging materials have to travel in order to deliver the finished<br />

product, one “theoretical” truck of simple 150g strawberry yogurt pots was moved over a<br />

thousand kilometers to supply her study area in Southern Germany. Böge’s analysis also<br />

shatters another often-heard pro-investment argument, namely that large-scale<br />

investments will bring about a more “rational” land use system by reorganizing<br />

production and distribution systems in more efficient ways. This statement typically<br />

triggers a heated debate over what exactly an “optimal” organization of a land use and<br />

transportation system would be – a debate that we can scarcely afford to enter at length<br />

here. However, the following key issues should be kept in mind with respect to regional<br />

transport infrastructure investments:<br />

First, a particular investment might ease congestion costs and hence improve<br />

travel times in the short run. However, by making travel cheaper, the investment is then<br />

also likely to encourage longer journey-making in the medium to long-term, hence<br />

inducing additional travel. And again, additional travel without concrete additional<br />

benefits is increasingly seen as undesirable. Depending on its nature, an investment<br />

might either encourage a greater clustering of activities around certain locations<br />

(agglomeration effects) or encourage a greater dispersal of economic activity (sprawl<br />

effect). The latter is generally considered to be both less efficient from a land-use<br />

perspective and responsible for more externalities. Effects can be contradictory,<br />

however. Another key analytical question is whether the investment triggers an overall<br />

increase of economic activity (win-win situation) or a just re-location of economic


56<br />

activity from one place to another (win-lose situation). The latter case is the essence of<br />

the so-called two-way road argument, which warns that “improved accessibility between<br />

two countries (and similarly, between cities, areas or regions) may sometimes benefit one<br />

of them to the disbenefit of the other.” (SACTRA 1999:2). Finally, there is one last<br />

irresolvable methodological challenge that brings us full circle and goes beyond<br />

challenging the productivity of transport investments to give recognition to the simple<br />

fact that travel itself can be both productive or unproductive, so that, depending on its<br />

nature, either an encouragement or a discouragement of movement is in order. This<br />

dilemma is most succinctly summarized in the comprehensive SACTRA report (1999:2-<br />

3), which is worth quoting at length:<br />

[T]heory suggests that there are a number of important mechanisms by which …<br />

transport improvement could, in principle, improve economic performance. […] In<br />

the search for empirical evidence, we find that direct statistical and case-study<br />

evidence on the size and nature of the effects of transport costs changes is limited.<br />

[…] The state of the art of this important field is poorly developed and the results do<br />

no offer convincing general evidence of the size, nature or direction of local economic<br />

impacts. […] Our studies underline the conclusion that generalisations about the<br />

effects of transport on the economy are subject to strong dependence on specific local<br />

circumstances and conditions.<br />

In sum, the discussion on the economic development effects of transport<br />

infrastructure investments is not likely to be concluded any time soon. Certainly, one’s<br />

answer also has much to do with one’s overall ideological background and/or<br />

professional training in particular disciplines. Neoclassical economists, of course,<br />

provide different answers than old time Keynesians, neo-Marxists or environmentalists.<br />

Note that these more contextual aspects of the discussion will be picked up in more detail<br />

in ensuing chapters.


57<br />

In the end, the fact that dominant notions about the economic development effects<br />

of transport are changing has much to do with the fact that the very notion of<br />

development is changing. Development is increasingly being understood as a concept<br />

that cannot be understood simply in narrow economic terms, but needs to encompass<br />

broader aspects including standards of living and the quality of the natural environment.<br />

In short: instead of economic development, we need to focus on sustainable development.<br />

The ensuing sections therefore present initial definitions of for the concepts of sustainable<br />

development and sustainable transport.<br />

2.3 “Sustainable Development”<br />

The words ‘sustainability,’ ‘sustainable’ and ‘sustainable development’ have<br />

become some of the most (ab)used terms of the last decades. The word sustainable first<br />

appeared around 1727. Its original meaning related mostly to agriculture and forestry,<br />

and can be defined as “of, relating to, or being a method of harvesting or using a resource<br />

so that the resource is not depleted or permanently damaged.” 4<br />

In this sense, it is a term<br />

with deep roots in ecology. 5<br />

Other definitions of sustainable are “something … able to be<br />

continued in its present form” or, more relevant for our context, “a way of using natural<br />

products so that no damage is caused to the environment.” 6<br />

Etymologically, the word<br />

sustain comes from the Old French sustenir and from the Latin sub-, from below, and<br />

tenere, to hold. 7<br />

Its broad etymological base also explains how the term can be used to<br />

mean almost anything:<br />

4 Merriam-Webster’s Collegiate Dictionary, online version http://www.britannica.com<br />

5 Beware of the all-too obvious pun.<br />

6 Cambridge International Dictionary, online version http://dictionary.Cambridge.org<br />

7 The American Heritage Dictionary of the English Language, Fourth Edition, 2000.


58<br />

The earliest meaning of sustain is to “support,” “uphold the course of” or “keep into<br />

being.” What corporate chief, treasury minister, or international civil servant would<br />

not embrace this meaning? Another meaning is “to provide with food and drink, or the<br />

necessities of life.” What underpaid urban worker or landless peasant would not accept<br />

this meaning? Still another definition is “to endure without giving way or yielding.”<br />

What small farmer or entrepreneur does not resist “yielding” to the expansionary<br />

impulses of big capital and the state, and thereby take pride in “enduring”?<br />

(O'Connor 1994:152, as quoted in Pezzoli 1997:549)<br />

Beyond being an increasingly (ab)used, “fuzzy” term (Markusen 1999), the<br />

concept of sustainability is closely related to the evolution of environmental debates and<br />

the environmental movement from the 1960s onward. Whereas the 1960s and the 1970s<br />

were initially only dominated by a growing concern over pollution issues, more profound<br />

critiques of the way in which conventional growth strategies exploited and often<br />

destroyed global environmental resources eventually came to the fore. The most famous<br />

account of the growing uneasiness among scientists is the Club of Rome report The<br />

Limits to Growth (Meadows, Randers et al. 1972). In many ways, the sustainability<br />

concept as it was developed in the 1980s provided an answer to the Club of Rome’s<br />

limits-to-growth argument in that sustainability inherently assumed that continuing<br />

economic growth was compatible with environmental protection. It thus broke the<br />

perception that environmental protection could only be achieved ‘at the expense of<br />

economic development,’ instead re-defining the two as interdependent and mutually<br />

reinforcing (Baker, Kousis et al. 1997:3).<br />

The best-known definition of sustainable development was put forward by the UN<br />

World Commission on Environment and Development in 1987 in the so-called<br />

Brundtland report (whose official title is Our Common Future). This report strongly<br />

influenced the future global environmental agenda, favoring a sustainability definition


59<br />

with a compatibility-oriented approach aiming to reconcile growth and environmental<br />

protection rather than defining the two as being in conflict. The Brundtland Commission<br />

defined sustainable development as “development that meets the needs of the present<br />

without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own needs.” This is<br />

now readily accepted by most countries and international institutions as a fundamental<br />

development goal.<br />

Of course, the Brundtland report is not without its critics. Langhelle (1999) has<br />

demonstrated that the assumed relationship between sustainable development and<br />

economic growth contained in “Our Common Future” has been overemphasized and lead<br />

to a “neglection of other vital aspects” of the concept. However, at present it will suffice<br />

to note that the Brundtland report was highly successful in influencing future policy<br />

making in the environmental area and beyond. The two key concepts of the Brundtland<br />

report were needs (especially the basic needs of the world’s poor) and limitations on the<br />

environment’s ability to meet humans’ (present and future) needs. The report<br />

subsequently identified the eradication of poverty in the development and the realignment<br />

of consumption patterns in the developed world as key elements of a global strategy for<br />

sustainability. It also struck a different tone than previous documents such as the IUCN’s<br />

1980 World Conservation Strategy by moving away from an ecology-based approach to a<br />

much more anthropocentric line of argument. The message of Our Common Future “is,<br />

above all, directed towards people, whose well-being is the ultimate goal of all<br />

environment and development policies” (WCED 1987:xiv, quoted in Baker, Kousis et al.<br />

1997:4).


60<br />

The underdevelopment debates of the 1980s were quickly superseded by<br />

environmental debates, and half a decade after Brundtland, the UNCED Earth Summit in<br />

Rio inaugurated environmentalism as “the highest state of developmentalism” (Sachs<br />

1993:3, quoted in Nygren 1998:201). Since the Rio Summit, a whole cluster of UN<br />

conferences, conventions and proceedings have concerned themselves with the subject of<br />

sustainable development and its environmental, social and economic dimensions (see<br />

table 2.1).<br />

Table 2.1. The “Rio Cluster” of UN Summits, Conferences, and Conventions<br />

o World Summit on Sustainable Development (WSSD) – “Rio +10” (Jo’burg, 2002)<br />

o UN Special Session “Istanbul +5” (New York, 2001)<br />

o Earth Summit +5 (New York, 1997)<br />

o Habitat II – “The City Summit” (Istanbul, 1996)<br />

o UN Conference on Trade and Development (Midrand, 1996)<br />

o Fourth World Conference on Women (Beijing, 1995)<br />

o World Summit for Social Development (Copenhagen, 1995)<br />

o Migratory and Straddling Fish Stocks (New York, 1995)<br />

o Conference on Population and Development (Cairo, 1994)<br />

o Sustainable Development of Small Island Developing States (Barbados, 1994)<br />

o World Conference on Natural Disaster Reduction (Yokohama, 1994)<br />

o World Conference on Human Rights (Vienna, 1993)<br />

o Earth Summit (Rio de Janeiro, 1992)<br />

o United Nations Commission on Sustainable Development Meetings (annually from<br />

1993)<br />

o UN Framework Convention on Climate Change – UNFCCC (New York, 1994),<br />

resulting in the Kyoto Protocol (Kyoto, 1997) and additional Conferences of the<br />

Parties (COPs)<br />

o Misc. International Conventions on Biodiversity, and Desertification<br />

Note: Details about these conferences and conventions including references to related<br />

literature, can be found on the internet at http://www.igc.apc.org/habitat/unproc/index.html,<br />

http://www.earthsummit2002.org/, and http://www.un.org/esa/sustdev/.<br />

Source: Pezzoli (1997), own additions


61<br />

Following the UNCED Rio Earth Summit, Agenda 21 became the international<br />

blueprint for sustainability. Energy efficiency, environmental protection, inter- and intragenerational<br />

equity and a long-term horizon emerged as major themes. An increasing<br />

number of international organizations began to subscribe to the concept, with major<br />

players including the United Nations Environment Programme and other UN agencies,<br />

the World Bank, the OECD as well as the European Union. To operationalize the<br />

concept without having one single commonly accepted definition proved difficult for<br />

these international organizations. The OCED, for example, circumvented the definitional<br />

problem by instead defining a series of policy goals forming the OECD’s core<br />

Sustainable Development Strategy. The list of nine goals combines typical sustainability<br />

calls ‘to promote worldwide economic growth,’ or ‘to integrate economic and<br />

environmental policies’ with other developmental agendas such as ‘to control population<br />

growth where it is excessive,’ or ‘to upgrade human and institutional resources’ (quoted<br />

in Gillespie 1998:95). The post-Brundtland phase was thus a time where the term<br />

sustainability was extensively broadened, rephrased and adapted. Both Pezzey (1989)<br />

and Pearce et al. (1989) provide longish lists with different definitions of sustainability<br />

developed in the 1980s, and the inflation of definitions certainly continued throughout the<br />

1990s. In their 1997 volume evaluating the politics of sustainable development within<br />

the European Union, Baker et al. develop a so-called “ladder of sustainable development<br />

in advanced industrial societies” that - among other things - distinguishes between<br />

approaches with anthropocentric versus eccocentric/biocentric philosophical<br />

underpinnings. Meanwhile, McManus (1996) differentiates as many as nine general<br />

approaches to sustainability. However, Lafferty (1995:223-224, mentioned in Baker,


62<br />

Kousis et al. 1997) makes the important point that despite (or rather: because of) its<br />

deficiencies as a consistent analytical or normative concept, sustainable development<br />

remains a highly popular and important political concept.<br />

Recent efforts at the United National Development Program (UNDP) have<br />

focused on definitions that approach the concept of development from the perspective of<br />

quality of life improvements (Qizilbash 2001). In pertaining theoretical works, notions of<br />

ethical universalism and of intergenerational equity are of particular importance (Anand<br />

and Sen 2000), as well as new approaches to the concept of living standards (Sen 1987).<br />

To this end, ever more sophisticated indicators are being developed in order to measure<br />

progress in this arena. Most prominent among them is the Human Development Index<br />

(HDI, see e.g. UNDP 1999). Nevertheless, even many economists are well-aware that<br />

the task at hand is not one of taking stock of any particular natural assets on earth. As the<br />

renowned economist Robert Solow noted in a lecture in 1992:<br />

The duty imposed by sustainability is to bequeath to posterity not any particular thing<br />

– with rare exceptions such as Yosemite, for example,-- but rather to endow them with<br />

whatever it takes to achieve a standard of living at least as good as our own and to<br />

look after their next generation similarly. We are not to consume humanity’s capital,<br />

in the broadest sense.<br />

(Solow 1992:15, quoted in Anand and Sen 1994)<br />

Other indicator programs are much less andocentric than the HDI, instead<br />

focusing on the quality of the environment thus partially reverting to more ecological<br />

interpretations of sustainability. The most relevant indicator program for transport and


63<br />

environment issues in Europe is the TERM program of the European Environment<br />

Agency which is now published annually (EEA 2001). 8<br />

Scientists often differentiate between a weak or minimal definition of<br />

sustainability that guarantees the avoidance of environmental catastrophe and a strong or<br />

maximal version that aims at preserving natural capital that cannot be replaced, thus<br />

leaving future generations the opportunity “to experience a level of environmental<br />

consumption at least equal to that of the present generation” (Jacobs, 1991, quoted in<br />

Kozeltsev 1998:134). Of course, since it was firmly inserted into the environmental<br />

debates in the 1980s, sustainability had already become much overused and turned into “a<br />

big, sloppy term for a big, complex subject” (Prugh, Costanza et al. 2000:2).<br />

At one end of the spectrum, economists have attempted to make the concept fit<br />

into their models and formulas, resulting in definitions that might even sounds humorous<br />

8 TERM stands for Transport and Environment Reporting Mechanism. The TERM process is steered jointly<br />

by the European Commission’s Directorate-General for Energy and Transport, the Directorate-General for<br />

Environment, Eurostat and the European Environment Agency (EEA). Interestingly, the report is in fact<br />

much more than a mere reporting mechanism. Instead, it reflects general attitudes of the EEA with regard<br />

to transport. Consider the following excerpt from its September 11, 2001 press release:<br />

Most of the report’s key indicators signal unfavourable trends or show that there is still a long way to go<br />

to reach policy targets for “greening” transport. The report warns that current trends point away from<br />

achieving the EU’s recently-announced objectives of breaking the link between economic growth and<br />

growth in transport, and of returning the market shares taken by rail, maritime and inland waterway<br />

transport to 1998 levels by 2010. As a shift towards greater use of cars and planes continues, passenger<br />

and freight transport is growing at a faster rate than the economy as a whole, bringing increasing threats<br />

to the environment and human health, it says. For example, growth in energy use and greenhouse gas<br />

emissions from transport is jeopardising the EU’s ability to meet its targets under the Kyoto Protocol on<br />

combating climate change. But there are also some positive trends, mainly due to advances in<br />

technology and fuels that have made new road vehicles less polluting. A significant improvement in<br />

urban air quality has resulted, although in many cities air quality still poses health risks and further<br />

improvement is needed. The energy efficiency of car transport has improved slightly over the past two<br />

decades, although low occupancy rates and the use of heavier and more powerful vehicles have partly<br />

offset fuel efficiency gains in new cars. There has been no increase, however, in the energy efficiency<br />

of freight transport by road and little corresponding change in rail or shipping. Air transport remains the<br />

least energy efficient mode of transport despite technological advances. The report argues that better<br />

integration of environmental considerations into all areas of transport policy-making is required to<br />

achieve progress towards a more environmentally sustainable transport system.


64<br />

to other social scientists. For example, contrast Rasmussen’s (1997:352) entirely<br />

process-oriented sociological interpretation:<br />

Sustainability is a process with a beginning but no end: and in considerable measure it<br />

is a social construct. … It is thus a matter of human imagination and dreaming as well<br />

as concrete technologies, tasks and policies<br />

with the reductionist formula for sustainability that Heal (2000:5) offers<br />

[Some economists] argued that sustainability is captured by a Rawlsian definition of<br />

intertemporal welfare. [And] welfare is maximized by maximizing the welfare of the<br />

least well-off generation. One can write this formally and succinctly as<br />

{ max feasible paths { min generations t { welfare t } }}.<br />

One key message regarding the sustainability concept forcefully voiced even by<br />

economists is the fact that markets to not adequately protect nature and public health.<br />

Thus calls for greater sustainability have typically gone hand in hand with caller for a<br />

greater role of the state in protecting the environment and human health. As Anand and<br />

Sen (1994:2) argue:<br />

the obligation of sustainability cannot be left entirely to the market. The future is not<br />

adequately represented in the market … and there is no reason that ordinary market<br />

behavior will take care of whatever obligation we have to the future. Universalism<br />

demands that the state should serve as a trustee for the interests of future generations.<br />

[Emphasis in the original.]<br />

Nevertheless, many scholars are rather defeatist with regard to the usefulness of<br />

the concept: “To put is crassly, consumers want consumptions sustained. Workers want<br />

jobs sustained. … With the term meaning something different to everyone, the quest for<br />

sustainability is off to a cacophonous start” (Norgaard 1994:11). 9<br />

9 The last two quotes are adapted versions from longer quotes presented in Prugh, Constanza and Daly<br />

2000:4.


65<br />

There are some common threads in all these definitions, however. Despite the<br />

vast spectrum of definitions, almost all relevant definitions conceptualize sustainability as<br />

a concept with three fundamental dimensions that can also be thought of as the three ‘e’s<br />

of sustainability: economy, environment/ecology and equity (i.e. society). This central<br />

and recurring distinction between different sustainability dimensions is commonly found<br />

in the literature (see figure 2.1). In a nutshell, the image implies that there is indeed a<br />

mode of development that can somehow balance the aims of economic growth,<br />

environmental protection and social equity in a benign and mutually beneficial way.<br />

If there is widespread dismay over the inherent vagueness of the concept, perhaps<br />

the best explanation for its success is precisely this ambiguity which enabled its<br />

promoters to integrate a vast array of policies and programs into the sustainability<br />

agenda. In fact, Maarten Hajer (1995), whose discourse analytical approach to<br />

environmental debates is discussed in more detail in later chapters, has long argued that it<br />

is precisely the relative superficiality and ambiguousness of sustainability argument that<br />

has assured the concept such widespread support. Even prior to the Rio Summit, Hajer<br />

characterized the concept of sustainable development as “not only an attempt to provide<br />

solutions to improve the objective state of the environment but also an effort to<br />

accommodate latent social conflict” (Hajer 1991, quoted in Whitelegg 1993:6). This<br />

interpretation rings ever more true today, with the term having suffered extremely<br />

inflationary use in policy papers throughout the world over the last decade.


66<br />

Figure 2.2 The Three Dimensions of Sustainable Development<br />

Environment<br />

Equity<br />

Economy<br />

2.4 “Sustainable Transport”<br />

Given its enormous emissions and its land use requirements, transport quickly<br />

became a major focus for concern within the larger discussions on sustainability. The<br />

environmental and social impact of transport are enormous. Transport is responsible for<br />

about 50 percent of global oil consumption, up to 90 percent of carbon monoxide,<br />

nitrogen oxide and hydrocarbon emissions in heavily trafficked urban areas (World<br />

Resources Institute 1996). Transport emissions are a both major contributor to global<br />

warming and a significant threat to human health. The WHO estimates that in European<br />

cities, 80,000 adult death every year are related to long-term exposure to traffic-related<br />

air pollution (WHO 1999:16). Noise from transport also has significant health impacts.<br />

About 65 percent of Europeans are exposed to noise levels of 55-65 dBLAeq over 24<br />

hours, which have shown to lead to serious annoyance, speech interference, and sleep<br />

disturbance (WHO 1999:17). Globally, over 500,000 people are killed in road accidents


67<br />

every year with vulnerable road users such as pedestrians and cyclists accounting for one<br />

third of deaths (World Bank 1996). 10<br />

Agenda 21 itself contained several specific transport policy suggestions, as did the<br />

1996 UN Habitat Global Plan of Action and numerous European policy documents.<br />

Even under a minimum definition, the dual requirement to minimize environmental<br />

impacts and make the most economic and equitable use of resources has been interpreted<br />

by most transport and land use planners to mean a favoring of higher density, compact<br />

land use-oriented along nodes of public transportation over lower-density uses that<br />

require individual motorization.<br />

Overall, there is a divide between those who believe<br />

that greater transport sustainability can be achieved through technological fixes, e.g.<br />

through greater fuel economy, alternative fuels, better or perhaps smaller engines, and<br />

those who believe that the transport problem needs to be addressed in a more<br />

comprehensive manner, e.g. through modal shifts to non-polluting modes, better land use<br />

planning, traffic management and calming (also see Whitelegg 1994:25).<br />

More generally, definitions for 'sustainable transport' follow a similar pattern as<br />

those for sustainability. As the World Bank (1996:4-5) explains:<br />

Economic and financial sustainability requires that resources be used efficiently and<br />

that assets be maintained properly. Environmental and ecological sustainability<br />

requires that the external effects of transport be taken into account fully when public<br />

or private decisions are made that determine future development. Social sustainability<br />

requires that the benefits of improved transport reach all sections of the community.<br />

(Italics in the original.)<br />

10 Figures are often controversial, both for industrial and developing countries. According to a recent<br />

ECMT press release, over 32,000 people were killed on the roads of Western Europe, and close to 16,000<br />

in Central Eastern Europe in 2000 (ECMT 2001:2). The WHO, however, presents more inclusive figures,<br />

speaking of 2 million traffic accidents in the European Region of WHO (which includes FSU countries)<br />

killing 129999 and injuring 2.5 million (Dora and Racioppi 2001:2 and WHO 1999:16).


68<br />

A recent definition provided by the European Conference of Ministers of<br />

Transport (ECMT 2000:7) 11<br />

also stressed all three dimensions, but emphasized the<br />

welfare aspect at the same time:<br />

The Objective of sustainable development is to maximise welfare, and provide a sound<br />

economic, social and environmental base for both present and future generations. ...<br />

The development of sustainable transport policies implies reconciling environmental,<br />

social and economic objectives and will require further improvement on a wide range<br />

of forms for inland transport. (my emphasis)<br />

Obviously, different stakeholder groups stress different dimensions of<br />

sustainability depending on their own particular bias. For example, the Sustainable<br />

Mobility Project of the World Business Council for Sustainable Development<br />

(WBCSD), 12 which is comprised of an illustrious grouping of major automobile and oil<br />

multinationals, predictably focuses on mobility, rather than transport, and defines<br />

sustainable mobility more as a fundamental human right subject to certain value<br />

limitations or ‘sacrifices’ than as a responsibility requiring urgent human action. In its<br />

voluminous Mobility 2001 report, the group defines sustainable mobility as “the ability to<br />

meet the needs of society to move freely, gain access, communicate, trade, and establish<br />

relationships without sacrificing other essential human or ecological values today or in<br />

the future” (WBCSD 2001:1.2).<br />

A much more skeptical, political economy interpretation of sustainable transport<br />

is presented by Baeten (2000:72):<br />

11 The inside cover of the ECMT publication 'Sustainable Transport Policies' notes that "Ministers from<br />

ECMT's 47 Member and Associate countries endorsed this approach, and this paper as a whole, at their<br />

Council meeting in Prague 2000" (ECMT 2000:4). (All EU member and candidate countries are also full<br />

ECMT Members.) The provided definition itself is a reiteration of definition provided in a OECD Policy<br />

Brief from 1998 (No. 8).


69<br />

Sustainable transport, then, can be defined as an attempt to reconcile, on the one hand,<br />

the economic imperatives of growth, competitiveness and profit seeking which are<br />

imposed upon producers of transport means, and, on the other hand, ecological values<br />

and norms. In other words, sustainable transport aims at tackling the environmental<br />

crisis without touching the economic strongholds of Western Society. (italics added)<br />

Note that Baeten’s transport-specific definition is embedded in very critical<br />

overall assessment of the meaning of Brundtland, which he credits with presenting a<br />

solution for the economy-ecology paradox which essentially lets “mightly economic<br />

monoliths” off the hook. His view of sustainable development is thus that of a deeply<br />

contested concept: “The political and economic world elite eagerly reacted to the<br />

optimistic, reconciling and harmonizing language of sustainable development that swept<br />

aside the underlying contradictions of the environmental policy process” (p.72).<br />

However, as we will see in more detail in later chapters, mainstream assessments<br />

are less pessimistic.<br />

When referring to transport, probably the best-known<br />

comprehensive definitions for sustainability are provided by the Vancouver Principles of<br />

Sustainable Transport. These principles were developed at the OECD Conference<br />

“Towards Sustainable Transportation” in Vancouver in 1996. The problem statement<br />

presented at the OECD conference in Vancouver stands in direct contrast to the WBCSD<br />

approach of focusing on mobility. Transport experts in Vancouver formulated the issue<br />

as follows (OECD 1996a):<br />

Our current transportation system is not on a sustainable path. Our admirable<br />

achievements in terms of mobility have come at some considerable environmental as<br />

well as social and economic cost. The challenge now is to find ways of meeting our<br />

transportation needs that are environmentally sound, socially equitable and<br />

economically viable. Accessibility, not mobility, is the issue.<br />

[Emphasis in the original.]<br />

12 The WBCSD, now a coalition of 150 international companies, spearheaded the business community’s<br />

response to the Rio Earth Summit. Chemical, automobile and oil multinationals such as Dupont, Ford,<br />

General Motors, Royal Dutch Shell, BP and DaimlerChrysler are major supporters of the WBCSD.


70<br />

The Vancouver principles are also more comprehensive than most definitions in<br />

that they move beyond the common - but also problematic (see e.g. Campbell 1996) -<br />

threefold definition of sustainability towards a ninefold definition that not only explicitly<br />

includes important aspects such as access, integrated planning and land and resource use,<br />

but also issues such as community responsibility and public participation, which always<br />

risk of being relegated to being afterthoughts rather than integral parts of the sustainable<br />

development principle. Table 2.1 presents an overview of the Vancouver principles.<br />

Evidently, the EU itself also considers the Vancouver principles to be relevant to<br />

decision-making on transport infrastructure investment in Central Europe. This is<br />

indicated by the following noteworthy detail: When the 8-page Phare Multi-Country<br />

Transport Program Newsletter (edited at DG Transport and Energy and published by the<br />

European Commission) ran an entire edition on the topic “Transport and the<br />

environment” in January 2000, these principles were printed on the back page of the<br />

newsletter in their entirety (i.e. including all definitions).<br />

The Vancouver principles have also provided the basis of additional work on<br />

sustainable transport by the OECD in Europe, and most notably for the recently<br />

completed OECD project on Environmentally Sustainable Transport (EST) which<br />

produced numerous workshop reports, guidelines as well as case studies. Within the EST<br />

project, the OECD produced the following environmental definition for sustainable<br />

transport (OECD 1996b:54):<br />

Transport that does not endanger public health or ecosystems and meets mobility<br />

needs consistent with (a) use of renewable resources at below their rates of<br />

regeneration and (b) use of non-renewable resources at below the rates of development<br />

of renewable substitutes.


71<br />

A pilot study and a special report on environmentally sustainable transport in<br />

Central Eastern Europe are also available (CEI 1999 and OECD 2000a).<br />

Table 2.2 The OECD’s Sustainable Transport Principles<br />

Principle OECD Definition<br />

1. Access People are entitled to reasonable access to other people, places, goods<br />

and services, as well as responsible information that empowers them<br />

towards sustainable transportation<br />

2. Equity Nations, states and the transportation community must strive to ensure<br />

social, interregional and inter-generational equity, meeting the basic<br />

transportation-related needs of all people including women, the poor,<br />

the rural, and the disabled. Developed countries must work together<br />

with developing economies to foster practices of sustainable<br />

transportation<br />

3. Individual All individuals and communities have a responsibility to act as<br />

& Community stewards of the natural environment, undertaking to make sustainable<br />

Responsibility choices with regard to personal movement and consumption<br />

4. Health and<br />

Safety<br />

5. Education<br />

and public<br />

participation<br />

6. Integrated<br />

Planning<br />

7. Land and<br />

resource use<br />

8. Pollution<br />

prevention<br />

Transportation systems should be designed and operated in a way that<br />

protects the health (physical, mental, and social well-being) and safety<br />

of all people, and enhances the quality of life in communities<br />

People and communities need to be fully engaged in the decisionmaking<br />

process about sustainable transportation, and empowered to<br />

participate. In order to do this, it is important that they be given<br />

adequate and appropriate resources and support, including<br />

information, about the issues involved as well as the benefits and costs<br />

of the array of potential alternatives<br />

Transportation decision-makers have a responsibility to pursue more<br />

integrated approaches to planning.<br />

Communities should be designed to encourage sustainable<br />

transportation and enhance access, as a contribution to pro viding<br />

comfortable and congenial environments for living. Transportation<br />

systems must make efficient use of land and other natural resources<br />

while ensuring the preservation of vital habitats and other<br />

requirements for maintaining biodiversity<br />

Transportation needs must be met without generating emissions that<br />

threaten public health, global climate, biological diversity or the<br />

integrity of essential ecological processes.<br />

9. Economic Taxation and economic polices should work for, and not against,<br />

well-being sustainable transportation, which should be seen as contributing to<br />

improvements in economic and community well-being. Market<br />

mechanisms should support fuller cost accounting, reflecting the true<br />

social, economic and environmental costs, both present and future, in<br />

order to ensure users pay an equitable share of costs.<br />

Source: Conference ‘Towards Sustainable Transportation,’ Vancouver, March 1996


72<br />

2.5 Two Ill-Defined Concepts?<br />

We have now seen how controversial theoretical debates on transport investments<br />

are. Overall, there is a continued ambiguity regarding the assumed relationship between<br />

transport investments and economic development (i.e. growth). We have also learned to<br />

question the internal consistency of the concept of sustainable development. The<br />

supposedly harmonious relationship between the “three dimensions of sustainability”<br />

namely economy, environment, and equity, remains the most problematic aspect of the<br />

concept. Most comprehensive definitions of the concept tend to broaden the definition to<br />

include a host of additional aspects, as is the case with the Vancouver definitions. Other<br />

definitions simply over-emphasize one of the three dimensions, typically skewing it in<br />

favor of economic goals.<br />

As we will see in later chapters, there is no single one European Union document<br />

that conclusively defines the term sustainable transport. It even took the European<br />

community ten years after the Rio Summit to finally to come up with an official<br />

Sustainable Development Strategy. Given the difficulty the international community has<br />

had in conclusively defining and operationalizing either of these concepts, this is hardly<br />

surprising. In the end, for any normative definition of an abstract concept such as<br />

sustainability to be acceptable for an institution such as the EU, it would always have to<br />

be tied this institution’s underlying rationales for policy-making. We therefore need to<br />

move away from a normative, definitional approach to the topic of sustainability towards<br />

a more structural one. We need to look at sustainability and sustainable transport as<br />

discourse. Such a discourse-centered approach is the theme of the following chapters.


73<br />

Printed Thursday, October 31, 2002<br />

Last amended on September 15, 2002<br />

CHAPTER 3<br />

Introducing the Notion of Discursive Frameworks<br />

3.1 Introduction: The Notion of a Dominant Discourse ......................................... 74<br />

3.2 From Three Definitions of Sustainability to Five Discursive Frameworks...... 77<br />

3.3 Modernity and Modernization: Some (Meta-)Theoretical Considerations....... 79<br />

3.3.1 A Discourse Analytical Approach to Planning & Policy-Making............ 79<br />

3.3.2 Modernity, Post-Modernity, Anti-Modernity ........................................... 83<br />

3.3.3 Reconceptualizing Planning and Policy-Making? .................................... 86<br />

3.3.4 The Environment As Discourse................................................................ 89<br />

3.3.5 Post-Modernism ? Post-Fordism and pro-modern ? pro-capitalist .......... 91<br />

3.4 The Notion of Discursive Frameworks............................................................. 93<br />

3.4.1 Discursive Frameworks vs. Paradigms..................................................... 93<br />

3.4.2 Discursive Frameworks vs. the “Ladder” of Sustainable Development... 97<br />

3.4.3 The Use of the Term “Frameworks” in the Political Science Literature .. 99<br />

3.4.4 Discursive Frameworks versus Epistemic Communities........................ 101


74<br />

“We are all Greens now” unattributed quote, Hajer 1995:14<br />

3.1 Introduction: The Notion of a Dominant Discourse<br />

Sustainable development is a rhetorical concept that is interpreted differently<br />

depending on the overarching framework people operate in. As we will see in the<br />

following chapters, sustainability definitions used by the European Union tend to favor<br />

interpretations that place economic growth at the center of the agenda. I will show how<br />

this is part of a particular environmental discourse related to the overall framework of<br />

ecological modernization, i.e. a framework that sees growth and environmental protection<br />

as compatible and a positive sum game. The overall aim of the next chapters is to<br />

categorize, question and/or re-interpret different underlying “rationalities” of planning<br />

and policy-making, focusing on the sectoral realm of sustainable transport and the<br />

geographical realm of the European Union.<br />

Chapter 2 confirmed the “Ill-Defined<br />

Concept” Proposition. It demonstrated the inherently vague nature of the terms<br />

sustainability and sustainable transport, and warned us that definitions and statements<br />

with regard to the two concepts are inherently contradictory. This provides us with a<br />

partial explanation of why EU decision-making in the transport sector is not consistent:<br />

there is still no proper definition of what a sustainable transport policy would entail.<br />

However, rejecting the concept of sustainable transport on the grounds that it is simply an<br />

ill-defined and internally contradictory concept does not help us to explain the nature and<br />

direction of the contradictions and inconsistencies in the case of EU transport policy. For<br />

example, how do we explain the fact that so many EU policy documents define modes<br />

such as combined transport, rail, and public transit as “more sustainable” yet ultimately<br />

concentrate EU transport infrastructure investments on highways and high-speed rail? In


75<br />

order to fully explain such systematic biases, one needs to focus not only on the rhetorical<br />

content of official definitions but also on the underlying rationales of EU transport sector<br />

decision-making.<br />

The main proposition for the next three chapters is the “Dominant Discourse”<br />

Proposition. This proposition assumes that the EU employs the concept of sustainable<br />

transport in the context of a discursive framework which favors (short and medium term)<br />

growth and efficiency objectives at the expense of equity and environmental preservation<br />

objectives. More precisely, I argue that EU transport sector decision-making is<br />

dominated by the discursive framework of ecological modernization. I define ecological<br />

modernization as a modernist model of development that is relatively successful in<br />

integrating a variety of environmental and social concerns into its framework, but that<br />

nevertheless privileges competitiveness and economic growth over alternative<br />

development goals.<br />

My ensuing interpretations of decision-making in the European Union heavily<br />

rely on the fundamental insight that decision-making rationalities are always expressed<br />

through discursive processes.<br />

Maarten Hajer (1995:44) has defined the term<br />

(environmental) discourse as “a specific ensemble of ideas, concepts, and categorizations<br />

that are produced, reproduced, and transformed in a particular set of practices and<br />

through which meaning is given to physical and social realities”. 1<br />

This has since become<br />

1 A few pages later, Hajer (1995:60) introduces three further definitions with regard to discourse worth<br />

noting:<br />

We will speak of discourse structuration if the credibility of actors in a given domain requires them to<br />

draw on the ideas, concepts, and categories of a given discourse, for instance, if actors’ credibility<br />

depends on the usage of the terms of ecological modernization in the domain of environmental politics.<br />

We will speak of discourse institutionalization if a given discourse is translated into institutional<br />

arrangements, i.e. if the theoretical concepts of ecological modernization are translated into concrete<br />

politices (i.e. shifting investment in mobility from road to rail) and institutional arrangements. … If


76<br />

a frequently quoted definition, and it is also in this vein that I employ the adjective<br />

discursive here.<br />

Discourses, I argue, are structured in different “discursive frameworks” each of<br />

which emphasizes different overarching themes and each of which has different<br />

analytical foci. I define a discursive framework as a theoretical approach consisting of<br />

an ensemble of underlying rationales and concepts that together form the intellectual<br />

backdrop for a set of policy responses and actions relating to a particular topic. Each<br />

discursive framework I identify is distinguished by its overarching theme, its unit of<br />

analysis, and its framework of action. 2<br />

Table 3.1 provides an overview of the five identified discursive frameworks for<br />

sustainable policy-making. These discursive frameworks will be discussed in more detail<br />

in Chapter 4. The rest of this chapter is devoted to “setting the stage” for this discussion.<br />

I first explain how and why I move away from the previous definitional search related to<br />

the three-dimensional concept of sustainability to a wider, structural analysis of<br />

environmental discourse. I then make a general distinction between three metatheoretical<br />

perspectives on social science research, namely modernity, post-modernity<br />

and anti-modernity, which variously influence the empirical foundations of the five<br />

discursive frameworks. After that, I differentiate the notion of a discursive framework<br />

from the notion of a paradigm, and explain the concept’s relation to the academic<br />

literature on advocacy coalition frameworks and on epistemic communities.<br />

these two conditions are satisfied, a discourse can be said to be hegemonic in a given<br />

domain.[Emphasis added.]<br />

2 If my definition uses the term “discursive framework” as essentially synonymous to “theoretical<br />

approach,” why am I introducing the neologistic term, on might ask? The key reason is that the generic<br />

term “theoretical approach” is variously used at the practical/methodological, theoretical and even at the<br />

meta-theoretical/epistemological levels. As section 3.4 explains, my “discursive frameworks” are meso-


77<br />

Table 3.1 Five Discursive Frameworks for Sustainable Policy-Making<br />

Theoretical<br />

Approach<br />

Overarching<br />

Theme<br />

Unit of<br />

Analysis<br />

Pro-<br />

Modern<br />

?<br />

Pro-<br />

Capitalist?<br />

Key Policy<br />

Relevance<br />

Ecological<br />

Modernization<br />

“Sustainable<br />

Growth”<br />

(Market)<br />

Economy<br />

Yes Yes Proactive,<br />

Competitive<br />

Action<br />

Reflexive<br />

Modernization<br />

“Risk<br />

Rationality”<br />

Society Yes Yes Precautionary<br />

Action<br />

Communicative<br />

Rationality<br />

Rationality<br />

People &<br />

Institutions<br />

Yes Yes /<br />

No<br />

Communicative<br />

Action<br />

Political<br />

Economy<br />

Equity &<br />

Social<br />

Justice<br />

Society &<br />

Space<br />

Yes / No No Re-distributive<br />

Action<br />

Renunciation<br />

Source: Own compilation<br />

Ecological<br />

Balance<br />

Nature Yes / No No Protective<br />

Action<br />

(Eco-centric)<br />

3.2 From Three Definitions of Sustainability to Five Discursive Frameworks<br />

For many advocates of the sustainability concept, my distinction of five different<br />

discursive frameworks – with ecological modernization being the dominant one in EU<br />

policy-making – might seem somewhat counter-intuitive. Conventionally, sustainability<br />

scholars argue that the three-dimensional nature of sustainable development presented in<br />

Chapter 2 (“efficiency” – “environment” – “equity”) can be ascribed to the fact that the<br />

level theoretical constructs located somewhere between Kuhn’s “paradigms” and Sabatier’s “policy theory<br />

frameworks,” and with a much greater affinity towards the former.


78<br />

concept aims to integrate aspects from three fundamentally different development<br />

“paradigms”. Campbell (1996), fortunately avoiding the use of the term paradigm,<br />

speaks of a “planner’s triangle of sustainable development” comprised of the three<br />

fundamental aims of environmental protection, economic development and social equity.<br />

This view is also exemplified by Masser, Sviden and Wegener (1992:35) in the<br />

Geography of Europe’s Future where they identify three main transport development<br />

“paradigms” in Europe which are often in conflict with each other: growth, equity and<br />

environment. They further equate these “paradigms” with conservative, socialdemocratic<br />

and green transport politics, respectively. Note that I consider the use of the<br />

term “paradigm” quite inappropriate in this context (also see section 3.5.1 below).<br />

Nevertheless, in my initial analyses of EU transport policy, I originally also planned to<br />

follow this more conventional three-part distinction. However, the discussion of the<br />

relationship between transport and economic development in Chapter 2 already indicated<br />

that rather than simply viewing the term sustainability as having three main, somehow<br />

complementary “dimensions” of growth, environment and equity, we have to instead<br />

consider several additional factors in the equation. For example, we have to somehow<br />

account for the fact that the very nature of capitalist development is undergoing profound<br />

changes. We also have to consider more process- and institutionally-oriented arguments<br />

related to “sustainable” decision making (transparency, participation). We have to also<br />

take into account that many scholars increasingly reject the concept of sustainable<br />

development. Finally, additional concerns related to the changing nature of rational<br />

decision-making in the context of globalization, multi-level governance and multilocation<br />

politics also need to be considered. This chapter therefore takes a fundamentally


79<br />

different approach, moving away from narrow three-part definitions of sustainability and<br />

sustainable transport. Instead of seeking to further define the concept of sustainability,<br />

and considering how EU policies measure up against this definition, I seek to describe<br />

and analyze the larger discursive framework in which EU definitions of sustainable<br />

transport are being formulated and advanced as policy. In a sense, I take the very<br />

existence of the tern “sustainable transport” as indicative of a larger phenomenon, namely<br />

the rise of environmental concerns in modern societies. We thus enter a much broader<br />

debate over different approaches to the environment and to development more generally.<br />

3.3 Modernity and Modernization: Some (Meta-)Theoretical Considerations<br />

3.3.1 A Discourse Analytical Approach to Planning & Policy-Making<br />

How can we restore the concept of rationality in light of post-empiricist/postmodern<br />

challenges? Such questions can hardly be avoided when taking a discursive<br />

approach. Many regard it as the core challenge for planning and policy-making in the<br />

21 st century (also see chapter 3). Rather befittingly, Frank Fischer and John Forester<br />

opened their 1993 volume on The Argumentative Turn in Policy Analysis and Planning<br />

with the following question: “What if our language does not simply mirror or picture the<br />

world but instead profoundly shapes our view of it in the first place?” One possible<br />

response is that we need to pay closer attention to rhetoric, albeit without forgetting<br />

reality (i.e. power relationships).<br />

Fuelled by the publication of Maarten Hajer’s (1995) well-argued and wellreceived<br />

book The Politics of Environmental Discourse, there has been a rapidly evolving<br />

literature on environmental discourses in planning and public policy. Its interdisciplinary


80<br />

influence is reflected in several recent articles in scientific journals relating to<br />

environmental studies, planning, geography, and even anthropology (Campbell 1996;<br />

Nygren 1998; Fischer and Hajer 1999; Lumley 1999; Ruzza 2000; Harper 2001). There<br />

is now also an emerging literature on sustainability discourses in the specific area of<br />

transport policy. 3<br />

More generally, in the wake of Foucault and other post-positivist<br />

critics, scholars of all disciplines have found it necessary to focus much more closely on<br />

the various discourses that both researchers and practitioners employ. Struggles over<br />

transport-infrastructure decision-making particularly clearly illustrate the use of different<br />

discourses and their consequences (see e.g. Flyvbjerg 1998; Sager 1999; Langmyhr 2000)<br />

Hajer (1995:43) warns that “discourse analysis has come to mean many different<br />

things in as many different places.” The Oxford English Dictionary (OED, 2 nd Edition,<br />

1989) defines the now prevailing sense of the word “discourse” as “a spoken or written<br />

treatment of a subject, in which it is handled or discussed at length.” The OED further<br />

defines “discourse analysis” as a special combined word pertaining to “a method of<br />

analyzing the structure of texts or utterances longer than one sentence, taking into<br />

account both their linguistic content and their socio-linguistic context” or to “[an]<br />

analysis performed using this method.” 4<br />

This is perhaps the most minimal definition of<br />

discourse analysis. As we will see in later chapters, both more text-oriented analyses<br />

searching for linguistic content (Chapter 5) and more thematic analyses searching for<br />

3 Although the authors of these scattered articles have not yet entered into a full-fledged debate with each<br />

other, this is foreseeable for the future. The journal European Planning Studies has been especially<br />

prominent in advancing the debate by publishing four key articles on the topic over the course of the year<br />

2000 alone (Sager 1999; Baeten 2000; Langmyhr 2000; Richardson and Jensen 2000). Other recent<br />

contributions have been provided by Willson (2001), Langmyhr (2001), and Vigar (2000; Vigar 2001).<br />

When analyzing automobility, rather than sustainability, Beckmann (2001a) even posits the emergence of a<br />

new "sociology of transport and mobility." See Chapter 4 for additional details on these authors.<br />

4


82<br />

“discourse coalitions” and “storylines”, while immensely attractive as an analytical<br />

method, is sometimes too lenient in its assumptions about initial stakeholder preferences.<br />

In my view, personal agency and deliberate agenda-setting by particular actors tend to<br />

disappear from view when structural discourses are over-emphasized. Consequently, the<br />

following chapters represent an attempt to “rescue” discourse theoretical approaches for<br />

theorists like myself who are extremely wary of overstating the social constructivist case.<br />

At this point, it is also necessary to emphasize a fundamental difference between<br />

at least two different camps of “discursively-minded” researchers in the field of planning<br />

and policy analysis. On one hand, there are researchers who, like myself, are interested in<br />

employing discourse-centered strategies to better understand the rationality of urban,<br />

regional, transport planning and/or environmental policy. In this case, discourse analysis<br />

is mostly seen as a means to an end. Closer attention to language is seen as a helpful<br />

device for revealing underlying rationales for decision-making and power relationships<br />

(see especially Hajer 1995; Richardson 1996; Flyvbjerg 1998; Baeten 2000). Note that<br />

for me, this means learning from Foucault and rejecting the excesses of instrumental<br />

rationality, but it does not necessarily mean adopting a full-blown poststructuralist<br />

position which questions rationality as such. In particular, it should not mean reneging<br />

on an overall political economy perspective which is predominantly concerned with<br />

issues of equity, redistribution and social justice.<br />

However, contrary to such more Foucault-oriented scholars, there is one other<br />

main strand of discourse theory. This second group of scholars relies heavily on the work<br />

of Jürgen Habermas. To them, the question of how discursive interaction is organized<br />

becomes itself the key question that determines what is “good” versus “bad” planning


83<br />

and policy-making. For these Habermasian adherents to the communicative rationality<br />

approach, the focus on discourse and rhetoric is itself the centerpiece of a new approach<br />

to planning and policy-making, and even to the social sciences more generally (for the<br />

realm of transport planning, see especially Sager 1999; Langmyhr 2000; Willson 2001).<br />

Here, discourse theory is no longer a means to an end. Rather, discourse and<br />

communicative rationality provide the solution to environmental and social equity<br />

struggles that we have been struggling with of late. Greater communicative rationality is<br />

assumed to result in greater equity and social justice and better environments. In sum, we<br />

have an entire theoretical approach that is strongly process-oriented at its core. We will<br />

come back to this important point during our detailed discussion of the different<br />

discursive frameworks in Chapter 4. For now, suffice to note that for communicative<br />

rationality scholars, Habermasian ideal speech situations usually seem more important<br />

than either Foucauldian discourses or Flyvbjergian power-rationalities. I, however,<br />

ultimately tend to stress the latter.<br />

3.3.2 Modernity, Post-Modernity, Anti-Modernity<br />

Above, I defined the EU’s dominant discursive framework of ecological<br />

modernization as a “modernist” model of development. Modernity and modernism are<br />

rather contested notions these days, and this categorization therefore deserves some<br />

additional explanation, also with regard to the other discursive frameworks I develop.<br />

Overall, one can differentiate between three different meta-theoretical<br />

perspectives on social science: pro-modern, post-modern and anti-modern views.<br />

Generally speaking, the rise of greater environmental awareness is frequently seen in


84<br />

conjunction with the decline of the modern(ist) research framework, or Modernity as a<br />

whole. At the origin of the “Modern Age of Reason” lies the development of the<br />

“scientific method” which eventually replaced the scholastic method of reasoning. 7<br />

More<br />

recently, scholars from a variety of disciplines, usually grouped under the generalizing<br />

labels of postmodernism and/or post-structuralism have rung in a new post-positivist era<br />

of (social) science, rejecting what some of them derogatively call Promethean visions of<br />

human progress and domination of nature. Instead, these scholars strive for an improved,<br />

social constuctivist understanding of Human Nature in the widest sense. Postmodern<br />

meta-theoretical approaches aim at countering essentialist, biological, overly normative,<br />

materialistic and universalizing understandings of human progress, and they label<br />

research approaches which they perceive as being guilty of this as “modernist.” Many<br />

postmodernists question the very notion of progress itself. Postmodern perspectives<br />

distinguish themselves by their explicit rejection of positivism 8 and of “grand theories”<br />

claiming to generate “singular, objective truths” about society and/or the environment.<br />

7 The “scientific method” is best described as a multi-step procedure consisting of 1) observation, 2)<br />

hypothesis-building, 3) hypothesis-testing through experiments and/or further observations, 4) hypothesismodification<br />

in light of obtained results, 5) repetition of steps 2-4 in order to eliminate discrepancies<br />

between hypothesis and observation. When consistency is obtained, a hypothesis may be considered a<br />

“theory.”<br />

8 Set off by Nicolas Copernicus’, Johannes Kepler’s and Galileo Galilei’s challenges to Ptolemian<br />

astronomy, the so-called “Scientific Revolution” of the Modern Age culminated in René Descartes’<br />

mechanical philosophy (and his Discourse on Method) and Isaac Newton’s creation of classical physics in<br />

the 17 th century. Yet it was not until the 19 th century that the early social scientist August Comte – who<br />

coined the term “sociology”! - developed his theory of positivism. According to positivist philosophy, the<br />

scientific method is the only source of knowledge. Comte explicitly rejected religion, traditional<br />

philosophy and any science that could not be reduced to direct observation. Moreover, Comte’s “Law of<br />

Human Progress” paralleled the evolution of the individual mind to the perceived evolution of human<br />

intellectual history, which – via progression through the theological and the metaphysical stages -<br />

culminated in the so-called “positive state” as the highest state of intellectual progress.


85<br />

Pointing to the ultimate contingency of all research settings, postmodernists emphasize<br />

heterogeneity, difference, and the multiplicity of viewpoints. 9<br />

In addition to this, there are a variety of scholars and practitioners adhering to a<br />

critical perspective which I would argue is more appropriately described as anti-modern<br />

than post-modern. Many of these writings are strongly environmentalist. Antimodernists<br />

would agree with postmodernists that the various “pro-modern” or<br />

“modernist” frameworks should be rejected, albeit for very different reasons. Where<br />

postmodernism emphasizes multiplicity for the sake of multiplicity, anti-modernism<br />

instead celebrates multiplicity only in the context of the ultimate one-ness of the universe.<br />

I see the crucial distinction between postmodern and anti-modern views in the perceived<br />

relationship between society and nature. This is a critical, but unfortunately often<br />

overlooked difference which goes a long way towards explaining recurring dissonances<br />

in environmentalist debates over sustainability. Post-modernists believe that the very<br />

concept of Nature is itself socially constructed, and as such they are mostly unable to<br />

develop normative concepts of sustainability. Anti-modernists, by contrast, typically<br />

have a rather fundamentalist view of Nature. From an anti-modernist perspective, the<br />

crucial failing of Modernism is the attempted “domination” of Nature, or, put more<br />

plainly, modern societies’ ecological insensitivity and lack of environmental<br />

consciousness. To anti-modernists, Nature is the tangible dimension of a larger world<br />

that has both material and spiritual aspects to it, and as such Nature is intrinsically worthy<br />

of protection. Sustainability and environmental protection thus become normatively<br />

definable and justifiable concepts.<br />

9 However, many social scientists thusly accused by postmodernists as being “modern”, “modernist,” or –<br />

even worse – as “positivist” would themselves reject these labels, or at least their negative connotations.


86<br />

An understanding of these different meta-theoretical differences is important since<br />

only three of the five identified discursive frameworks, namely ecological modernization,<br />

reflexive modernization, and communicative rationality can be said to operate as<br />

modern(ist) frameworks in the sense that they do not reject the Enlightenment project and<br />

the Rational model. The Ecological Modernization framework is the most unabashedly<br />

modernist framework of the five. Within the Reflexive Modernization framework, Ulrich<br />

Beck predicts the rise of new “counter-modernities” but nevertheless assumes that these<br />

will arise as a result of a break within modernity, rather than as an indication of its end.<br />

Meanwhile, Communicative Rationality approaches base their discursive framework on<br />

Jürgen Habermas’ Enlightenment-inspired ideas of communicative action and ideal<br />

speech situations (see especially Habermas 1984). By contrast, the Political Economy<br />

framework unites an amalgam of various pro-modern, post-modern and even anti-modern<br />

views all aimed at formulating a broad range of arguments for greater social and<br />

environmental justice in decision-making. Last but not least, the renunciation framework<br />

features strongly nature-focused approaches such as Deep Ecology, radical<br />

environmentalism or Gaia, which could be categorized as anti-modern.<br />

3.3.3 Reconceptualizing Planning and Policy-Making?<br />

To date, the modernity – post-modernity debate continues to rage in the planning<br />

and public policy literature at full speed (see e.g. Brand 1999; Fainstein 2000;<br />

Allmendinger 2001; Allmendinger 2002a), with some even proclaiming a “postpostmodernist”<br />

perspective (Turner 1996; Alexander 2000). Although planning as a<br />

discipline was once deemed to be a bastion of instrumental rationalism and positivism,<br />

Also see the note on Sabatier’s Advocacy Coalition Frameworks later in this chapter.


87<br />

Allmendinger (2002b:77), in a recent review article on typologies of planning, now notes<br />

the existence of a “post-positivist domination of planning theory in recent years …<br />

[whose] impact through various guises including collaborative, postmodern and neopragmatic<br />

approaches has been significant.”<br />

Post-modern meta-theoretical arguments are at the same time immensely<br />

important and greatly problematic for anyone attempting to re-conceptualize planning<br />

and policy-making processes at the beginning of the 21 st century. The practical relevance<br />

of post-modern theories for planning and policy-making is primarily in challenging their<br />

technocratic and elitist traits. On a theoretical level, Foucauldian discourse theory is now<br />

increasingly being posited as an alternative to Habermasian communicative rationality in<br />

planning theory debates, thus indicating the growing influence of postmodern discourses<br />

in the discipline (Richardson 1996).<br />

On one hand, post-modern approaches are certainly correct to sharply criticize the<br />

negative social and environmental consequences of industry-led modernization. It was<br />

particularly the inability of the modern state and its multi-layered institutions to<br />

adequately respond to global environmental challenges that prompted post-modernist and<br />

anti-modernist scholars to reject the Enlightenment project and Modernity. On the other<br />

hand, by calling an end to all aspects of Modernity, and, most importantly, by denying<br />

the possibility of some form of “enlightened rationality” (however redefined), it seems<br />

that post-modernists are often throwing out the baby with the bathwater. Although<br />

rightfully criticizing instrumental rationality, many postmodernist analyses leave us with<br />

few alternative visions as to how restore faith in the possibility of benevolent, futureoriented,<br />

“rational” decision-making. This presents an immense dilemma for planners


88<br />

and policy-makers who are dependent on such visions to guide their actions. Planners<br />

and policy-makers have been particularly vulnerable to post-modern attacks since the<br />

goal- and progress-oriented nature of their professions traditionally put them in the promodern<br />

camp. Planners and policy-makers, according to postmodernist critics, are guilty<br />

of having produced “totalizing discourses” that disregarded the dialectical relationship<br />

between man and nature and the contradictory nature of capitalist development.<br />

This is of course a vastly oversimplified critique. Put more appropriately, the<br />

planning and policy-making professions have always been deeply rooted in what Gleeson<br />

(2000) termed “the radical political-ethical vision of the Enlightenment.” It does not<br />

follow, however, that planning and policy-making necessarily therefore need to be<br />

modernist activities oblivious to contradictions and flaws in Western patterns of thought.<br />

Particularly with regard to aesthetic values and urban design, planning has often been<br />

anti-modernist. 10<br />

Without wishing to enter into a lengthy debate over these contested<br />

notions, I therefore should state that for the purposes of this study, I consider the<br />

postmodern allegations against the modernist, rationalist foundations of planning and<br />

policy-making only partially relevant and, more importantly, partially incorrect. The<br />

Enlightenment tradition might be guilty of privileging certain (Western) patterns of<br />

thought over others, but in the end, it was thanks to Enlightenment followers such as<br />

Hegel and Marx that we were able to overcome the boundaries of Cartesian rationality<br />

(built into classical physics). That is: it was precisely the Enlightenment thinkers who<br />

posited dialectics and dialectical argumentation as an alternative to previous, ontological<br />

systems of thought and therefore opened the path to new forms of knowledge, resulting in<br />

10 This is witnessed by various communitarian traditions in planning as well as most recently by the New<br />

Urbanism movement in the United States, which is almost antithetical to modernist architectural theory.


89<br />

everything but one-sided interpretations of the world. In this larger context, present<br />

(planning theory) debates over whether the thusly labeled “postmodern” Foucauldian<br />

discourse analysis is preferable to “modern” Habermasian communicative rationality<br />

approaches appear of secondary interest, especially since the two seemingly adversarial<br />

theoretical camps are ultimately joined in their aim to empower disadvantaged interests.<br />

Speaking on a more pragmatic level, recognizing sustainability as a contingent,<br />

discursive, rather than normative concept, and understanding material realities as being<br />

socially constructed, does not resolve existential, philosophical debates over power and<br />

rationality. Neither can we afford to shortcut related political discussions over how to<br />

conceive of a just – and justly-governed – society by simply reverting to a celebration of<br />

multiple viewpoints. Given that my own visions of sustainable planning and policymaking<br />

remain guided by the central challenge of achieving a just, responsible, equitable<br />

(re-) distribution of power and material resources, I still see myself as mostly working in<br />

the political economy tradition.<br />

3.3.4 The Environment As Discourse<br />

In the social sciences, “the environment,” “ecology” and “nature” have recently<br />

been identified as new “global narratives” that fundamentally transform contemporary<br />

policy-making. Many scholars go even further in postulating that a new “master<br />

narrative of the environment” has replaced the former “master narrative of<br />

enlightenment” (Lyotard 1984). And significantly, this new “ecology masterframe” has<br />

transformed the nature of political debate, not only in the more narrow field of<br />

environmental policy-making, but of all political discourse (Eder 1996). Resource


90<br />

scarcity, environmental risk and pollution are major themes in such environmental<br />

conflicts. Interpreted anthropologically as a discourse that is intrinsically trans-cultural,<br />

environmentalism also has been looked at as a positive form of globalization (e.g. Milton<br />

1995). The internationalization and institutionalization of environmentalist arguments<br />

into most relevant political and social spheres can also be viewed as a major success of<br />

global activism, fuelled by both governmental and non-governmental actors. The<br />

international arena of environmental protection now has its own dynamic, developed<br />

thanks to such diverse factors such as global policy-learning, a proliferation of nongovernmental<br />

actors, increased coverage of environmental issues in the global media, an<br />

overall tendency towards policy convergence as well as a periodic appearance of socalled<br />

leading-edge countries (Vorreiterländer) (Jänicke and Weidner 1997). 11<br />

It is<br />

noticeable that, while the potential of environmentalist narratives in forging grassroots<br />

coalitions and in bringing together and empowering non-governmental activists from a<br />

wide variety of ethnic and political backgrounds has been widely documented (e.g.<br />

Lipshutz 1996), the same discourses are now increasingly employed by scientific,<br />

governmental and corporate bodies. These institutions are sometimes accused of coopting<br />

the grassroots interests that were more genuinely working to protect the natural<br />

environment (Harper 2001). Harré et al. (1999:vii) coined the catch-all term<br />

“Greenspeak” to signify “all the ways in which issues of the environment are presented.”<br />

They posit it as a new environmental “lingua franca,” and suggest that the globalized<br />

media industry played a pivotal role in formulating a new environmental discourse that is<br />

new in both its universality and its quality. Harré et al also assume a “globalization of<br />

11 Despite their positive assessment, however, Jänicke and Weidner nevertheless acknowledge the<br />

continued difficulties of translating the developed environmental potential into action. A mere consensus


91<br />

green consciousness” as the result of this universalizing discourse (p.20). At other times,<br />

however, they are quick to point out that Greenspeak does ultimately not represent one<br />

unified voice, but rather “new worldwide cluster of dialects.”<br />

In summarizing recent literature on the topic, one can note a tension between two<br />

types of environmental discourse analysis. On one hand, there are very linguisticallyoriented<br />

scholars who are strong believers in the social constructivist research framework<br />

and who employ environmental discourse analysis because they believe that all social<br />

action can only be understood discursively (e.g. Harré, Brockmeier et al. 1999). On the<br />

other hand, there are more orthodox Foucauldian scholars who remain careful to still<br />

relate the discerned discourses back to social and political power relations (e.g. Darier<br />

1999). The former sort of analysis is most frustrating for planners and policy-makers in<br />

that it has the greatest difficulty in moving from critique to recommendation. The<br />

concluding paragraphs of such studies typically call for “greater rationality,” or “clearer<br />

argumentation,” forgetting that the art of persuasion in planning and policy-making does<br />

not necessarily imply that the most rational argument is necessarily the most attractive to<br />

decision-makers. 12<br />

3.3.5 Post-Modernism ? Post-Fordism and pro-modern ? pro-capitalist<br />

The overview in table 3.1 not only distinguishes the various discursive<br />

frameworks with regard to their relationship to modernity, but also with regard to<br />

capitalism. We have already noted in the previous chapter that during the last three<br />

on technical standards, rather than visionary environmental policy-making is often the result.<br />

12 Rydin (2000) makes similar points in her excellent book review on the two cited works. Especially in this<br />

last point, there is a strong affinity between studies of environmental policy-making written in discourse


92<br />

decades, the very nature of capitalist development has changed dramatically, deeply<br />

affecting all sectors of society, including transportation. Scholars within all of the five<br />

discursive frameworks discussed differ significantly both in the degree to which they see<br />

current changes as problematic and to which they reject capitalist systems more<br />

generally. Practically everyone acknowledges that current regimes of production and<br />

consumption are undergoing profound changes. Some even conflate the rise of post-<br />

Fordist flexible modes of production and consumption with the rise of post-modern<br />

cultural forms emphasizing multiplicity and discontinuity (see especially Harvey 1989).<br />

I need to stress, however, that one need not be a postmodernist in order to analyze and<br />

anticipate the rise of post-Fordists, post-capitalist and/or post-industrial societies. Many<br />

scholars grouped below under the ecological modernization label would reject<br />

postmodernist ideas – both at the (meta)-theoretical and at the design level – yet<br />

emphasize the growing importance of flexible, networking systems over linear,<br />

hierarchical structures. Meanwhile, many Marxist-influenced approaches, grouped here<br />

under the general heading of political economy approaches, can be said to be Post-<br />

Fordists in the sense that they critically analyze late Capitalism and its post-Fordist traits.<br />

Yet most Marxists reject post-modern interpretations of socio-economic change. Despite<br />

their explicit rejection of the capitalist development model, Marxist-oriented scholars<br />

typically remain epistemologically pro-modern in the sense that they continue to believe<br />

in some version of historical materialism, subsequently finding that the postmodern<br />

“reduction of everything to fluxes and flows, and the consequent emphasis upon the<br />

transitoriness of all forms and positions has its limits” (Harvey 1996:7). There are, of<br />

analytical tradition and many studies of urban and regional policy-making written in the communicative<br />

planning theory tradition.


93<br />

course, also scholars propagating a “postmodern Marxism” (see e.g. Gibson-Graham,<br />

Resnick et al. 2001) as well as many other political-economy scholars which consciously<br />

root themselves within the postmodern tradition. This explains why the columns “promodern”<br />

and “pro-capitalist” in Table 3.1 are not congruent with each other, and why<br />

some of the fields contain yes/no categorizations.<br />

3.4 The Notion of Discursive Frameworks<br />

3.4.1 Discursive Frameworks vs. Paradigms<br />

Most researchers use the term “paradigm” whenever they wish to connote a<br />

fundamental shift or difference in the way that research and/or policy-making is being<br />

framed. The term was first popularized by Thomas Kuhn in his famous book The<br />

Structure of Scientific Revolutions (1970). 13 In common usage, the term “paradigm” is<br />

now frequently understood to mean “worldview”. Consider the following uses of the<br />

term among many researchers writing on sustainable (transport) development and<br />

environmental policy (all emphases are mine):<br />

The 1987 Brundtland Report “Our Common Future” can be seen as one of the<br />

paradigm statements of ecological modernization.<br />

(Hajer 1995:26)<br />

There seems to be widespread agreement that environmental policy has undergone<br />

substantial changes in the past 10-15 years … Two ‘paradigms’, in particular, have<br />

been used to describe these changes: ecological modernization and sustainable<br />

development. (Langhelle 2000:303)<br />

One of the major efforts of planning theory has been to attempt to define what<br />

planning is, through the development of paradigms of planning thought. However, we<br />

have yet to see a universally accepted paradigm.<br />

(Richardson 1996:10)<br />

13 The first edition of the book was published in 1962, but the 1970 edition is more useful since it contains<br />

an illuminating 1969 post-script from the author in response to theoretical discussions since the original<br />

publication.


94<br />

In a market-oriented paradigm, we may expect that the central values are likely to<br />

follow the needs of the market.<br />

(Dabinett and Richardson 1999:233)<br />

In transport planning the synoptic paradigm still represents a barrier towards<br />

acknowledging the importance of rhetoric.<br />

(Langmyhr 2000:684)<br />

Communicative rationality offers a new paradigm for transportation planning.<br />

(Willson 2001:1)<br />

Goodwin et al. (1991) suggest that the [UK] road traffic forecasts of 1989 could be the<br />

key factor, ‘the watershed’, in bringing about a change in attitudes and approaches to<br />

transport planning. … They can be seen retrospectively as the central factor in<br />

facilitating a policy, or indeed a paradigm shift.<br />

(Vigar 2000:22)<br />

The first and theoretical part of [the Ph.D. thesis] draws a detailed picture of<br />

automobility as a modern mobility paradigm.<br />

(Beckmann 2001a:1)<br />

This list of quotes could easily be extended indefinitely. We will come back to<br />

most of the above statements later in the chapter. The last authors in particular imply that<br />

paradigm shifts are mainly related to changing attitudes of researchers and/or policymakers.<br />

This is not entirely incorrect but highly misleading. The key distinguishing<br />

feature of a paradigm is that it provides a new meta-theory, i.e. a larger explanatory<br />

framework that serves to explain many sub-theories. Most scholars today, however,<br />

employ the term only at the level of middle-range theorizing and theory-building. To<br />

boot, the diagnosed changes are often rather incremental, non-revolutionary, and<br />

sometimes largely amount to wishful thinking on the part of the diagnosing scholars as<br />

far as actual practice is concerned. 14<br />

Note that for a meta-theory to become a new<br />

paradigm, as defined in the Kuhnian sense, it also has to be accepted by a community of


95<br />

practitioners and a majority of practitioners subsequently needs to develop a pertaining<br />

body of what they regard as successful practice. Kuhn’s phenomenological evolutionary<br />

scheme described the history of natural science as a progression of periods of so-called<br />

normal science broken by periods of radical and revolutionary change leading to new<br />

paradigms. Science is understood here as a process of searching for fundamental<br />

principles governing cause and effect in the universe, and scientific knowledge is thought<br />

to be attainable via use of scientific methods such as hypothesis building, repeatable<br />

experiments and observation. Yet most researchers ignore that Kuhn’s analysis really<br />

only pertained to the history of the natural sciences, and that the notion of paradigm<br />

cannot so easily transferred to the social sciences. As Muller (1998:287) summarizes:<br />

Disciplines in the natural sciences have illustrated the validity of his paradigmatic<br />

principles by applying those principles to their fields of activity. The rigorous<br />

application of Kuhn’s formulation of in social science disciplines is, however, a<br />

different proposition. The intrinsic attributes of the human sciences are not congruent<br />

with those in the natural science domain, nor – by logical inference – with those of the<br />

paradigm.<br />

Bent Flyvbjerg (2001) equally argues that the case is fundamentally different for<br />

the social sciences. In his recently translated book Making Social Science Matter he<br />

comes to the following conclusion:<br />

The social sciences do not evolve via scientific revolutions, as Kuhn says is the case<br />

for the natural sciences. Rather, as pointed out by Hubert Dreyfus, social sciences go<br />

though periods where various constellations of power and waves of intellectual<br />

fashion dominate, and where a change from one period to another, which on the<br />

surface may resemble a paradigm shift, actually consists of the researchers within a<br />

given area abandoning a “dying” wave for a growing one…. Not paradigm shifts but<br />

rather style changes are what characterize social science: it is not a case of evolution,<br />

but more of fashion.<br />

(Flyvbjerg 2001:30) 15<br />

14 This is particularly true for the case of “communicative rationality” in transport planning. Also see<br />

below.<br />

15 Note that Flyvbjerg is of course employing a very Foucauldian critique here. He even continues the<br />

above paragraph with a quote from Foucault: “Foucault poses the questions of whether it is reasonable at


96<br />

While Flyvbjerg’s claim that social science is ruled by different waves of<br />

“fashion” seems a bit overstated, his polemic statement nevertheless underscores the<br />

urgent need to develop a term distinct from the notion of “paradigm” to connote<br />

fundamental differences in the way that social scientists and professionals intellectually<br />

frame, conceptualize and apply their work. These described differences can, but need<br />

not, be directly linked to meta-theoretical, epistemological discussions about<br />

postmodernist challenges and the (im)possibility of conducting doing valid, objective,<br />

true social science research. In either case, it seems preferable to avoid the use of the<br />

term paradigm. Taylor (1999), in an essay that analyzes intellectual changes in Anglo-<br />

American town planning developments from 1945 onwards, also comes to the conclusion<br />

that even the important shift from “modernist” to so-called “postmodernist” planning<br />

theory is “a significant development but no paradigm shift”. I find Taylor’s (1999:329)<br />

argumentation convincing:<br />

Of course, we are not compelled to adopt the strong, fundamentalist conception of<br />

paradigms … It is possible to use the concept in a weaker, more generous sense to<br />

describe shifts of thought which are significant, but not necessarily fundamental to<br />

people’s world view or conceptual scheme. …. However, … we need to be alert to the<br />

dangers of over-using the concept. If every twist and turn in planning thought over the<br />

past fifty years is described as another paradigm shift, the very notion of ‘paradigm<br />

shift’ becomes superfluous. I therefore favor the use of the term in its ‘purer’, more<br />

strict (and more restricted) sense.<br />

According to Muller, Taylor, and, most recently and most emphatically,<br />

Flyvbjerg, it is therefore incorrect to speak of a “paradigmatic shift” every time social<br />

science theory and/or their resulting policy approaches undergo significant change. I<br />

all to use the label “science” for this kind of activity. Even the expression ‘body of knowledge’ is too<br />

pretentious for Foucault: ‘let us say, to be more neutral still … body of discourse.’” (The quote is taken


97<br />

strongly agree with these authors that no matter how dramatic these changes may seem,<br />

they are not paradigmatic in the strict Kuhnian sense. 16<br />

And in the end, the described<br />

differences in the belief systems are not so much successive as parallel phenomena, and<br />

they are altogether less meta-theoretical and epistemological than socio-political in<br />

nature. This is why I revert to the term “discursive framework” and define it in the above<br />

described manner. Note that this neologism also accounts for the fact that it is not only<br />

the ensemble of theories embodied in a framework that matters, but also the particular<br />

way in which these are organized as a body of discourse.<br />

3.4.2 Discursive Frameworks vs. the “Ladder” of Sustainable Development<br />

Probably one of the best known and most widely distributed contributions to the<br />

topic of sustainable development in the EU is the edited volume The Politics of<br />

Sustainable Development – Theory, policy and practice within the European Union.” In<br />

the introductory chapter to this volume, Baker at al (1997:8) propose the following:<br />

The diversity of policy options associated with the different meanings attributed to<br />

sustainable development can best be seen in terms of a Ladder. … This enshrines a<br />

number of alternative frameworks for putting sustainable development into practice:<br />

the treadmill approach; weak sustainable development; strong sustainable<br />

development; and the Ideal Model. … The variety of approaches to sustainable<br />

development are an indication of differing ideological beliefs about the natural world,<br />

which for simplicity can be divided into the ‘anthropocentric’ and ‘ecocentric’<br />

positions.<br />

from Foucault’s The Order of Things (1970), whose original French title is Les Mots et les choses. Une<br />

archéologie des sciences humaines (1966)).<br />

16 However, Mastermann (1970)) points out that even Kuhn himself uses the term “paradigms” in at least<br />

20 different ways. Taylor (1999:342) also refers us to Kuhn’s postscript to his original essay to point out<br />

differences in Kuhn’s use of the term. Nevertheless, although some of Kuhn’s uses are indeed less<br />

fundamental than others, all of them are still narrower uses than those now common in the social science<br />

literature.


98<br />

The book then proceeds to present a table detailing a four-step “Ladder of<br />

Sustainable Development in advanced industrial societies” that ranges from an entirely<br />

pro-growth, business-as-usual “treadmill” approach to a an entirely eco-centric/biocentric<br />

“ideal model”. So why, one might ask, did I renege on the convenient option of simply<br />

using this pre-existing typology for my study? The reason is simple: I ultimately found<br />

the “Ladder” typology to be insufficient for explaining the various policy preferences of<br />

key EU stakeholders. In particular, Baker et al’s “Ladder” strongly parallels positive,<br />

progressive attitudes towards matters that are not strictly environmental (local selfsufficiency,<br />

democratization, participation, redistribution) with positive attitudes for<br />

“stronger” environmental sustainability. In my view, their “Ladder” thereby somewhat<br />

too cleverly conflates the key dimensions of “ecology and “equity”, and thus in turn<br />

downplays the persistence of rather divergent views on society, nature, and the<br />

relationship between the two. Not every grass-roots citizen organization is automatically<br />

interested in protecting the environment.<br />

In the end, the key differences between the two typologies are as follows: My<br />

mainstream discursive framework of “ecological modernization” more or less occupies<br />

the ladder range between “weak” and “strong” sustainability, which, as Baker et al note,<br />

focus on end-or-pipe to clean technologies, are based on a market-reliant to somewhat<br />

regulated economy, and which favor certain changes in patterns of production and<br />

consumption, to name but a few elements. My “renunciation” framework is roughly<br />

congruent with the environmental elements of the “Ideal Model” in the “Ladder.” Yet<br />

my three other discursive frameworks, i.e. “reflexive modernization,” “communicative<br />

rationality,” and “political economy,” have no counterpart in the “Ladder” typology.


99<br />

Instead, Baker et al. subsumes these perspectives under the various non-ecology-oriented<br />

elements of the “strong” or the “ideal” sustainability model. Meanwhile, Baker et al.’s<br />

“treadmill” approach at the anthropocentric end of the “Ladder” does not appear in my<br />

typology at all, since I find that an approach which propagates “exponential growth,”<br />

“resource exploitation,” and no policy or institutional change at all, should be more<br />

appropriately be characterized as non-sustainability and thus be categorized as standing<br />

outside any sustainability typology.<br />

3.4.3 The Use of the Term “Frameworks” in the Political Science Literature<br />

My decision to coin and define the term “discursive framework” to describe<br />

policy-relevant differences in socio-political belief systems among scholars and decisionmakers<br />

also has the unfortunate disadvantage that the term “framework” has been<br />

extensively used, and often re-defined, in the political science literature that focuses on<br />

the analysis of policy-processes. Rein and Schön, for example, define the term framing<br />

as a way of selecting, organizing, and interpreting of a complex reality to provide<br />

guideposts for knowing, analyzing, persuading and acting, so that a frame provides a<br />

perspective from which to make sense and act upon an amorphous, ill-defined<br />

problematic situation (see especially Rein and Schön 1994:263; for an article about a<br />

radical “reframing” of transport policy see Dudley and Richardson 1998). Fortunately,<br />

this does not necessarily challenge my use of the term framework. Moreover, Andrew<br />

Moravcsik’s (1999:19) decision to call his intergovernmentalist approach “a rationalist<br />

framework of intergovernmentalist cooperation” is also clearly delineated and thus<br />

should thus not lead to any confusion. He himself clarifies that he employs “the term


100<br />

framework (as opposed to theory or model) … to designate a set of assumptions that<br />

permit us to disaggregate a phenomenon we seek to explain.”<br />

More problematic, however, is the fact that Sabatier (1988; 1998), the volume<br />

edited by Sabatier (1999) and many scholars in the relevant literature all heavily rely on<br />

the term “frameworks” to categorize different policy theory approaches. In light of my<br />

own definition of the term, this must be regarded as an unfortunate linguistic<br />

circumstance, since my own definition is neither explicitly built on an elaboration or<br />

adaptation of Sabatier’s concept of advocacy coalitions, nor does it depend on any of the<br />

other six select policy theory frameworks recognized by Sabatier as “legitimate” tools for<br />

the “scientific” analysis of policy processes. Sabatier’s major contribution to policy<br />

analysis consists of a systematic search for concepts of policy learning in the context of<br />

what he calls “advocacy coalitions.” Advocacy coalitions can be comprised of a mélange<br />

of interest groups, administrative agencies, analysts, researchers, journalists and other<br />

stakeholders with an interest in the policy sector (Sabatier 1988:138). Yet while the<br />

advocacy coalition framework is doubtless a very useful, actor-oriented model that helps<br />

to explain both consistencies and discontinuities in the policy process, it is not a<br />

framework – let alone a discursive one – in the interdisciplinary, discipline-transcending<br />

sense that I employ the term in this study. Rather, it represents but one of several<br />

analytical frames within the particular discipline of political science/public policy. 17 In<br />

Sabatier’s case, “frameworks” represent methodologies that are consciously applied by<br />

17 It should also be noted that Sabatier’s neo-positivist, anti-constructivist and U.S. centric bias by now has<br />

been widely discussed in the literature (see especially Dudley, Parsons et al. 2000). Far from denying the<br />

importance of his contribution to the field of public policy, I agree that Sabatier’s overall perspective<br />

remains quite limited. Alternative, less rationalist approaches to policy analysis are simply dismissed, not<br />

refuted. To put it in Wayne Parsons unvarnished terms: “To ignore the kinds of idea [sic] associated with<br />

what has become known as the ‘argumentative turn’ (Fischer and Forester 1993) in policy analysis, for<br />

instance, is just plain silly.” See page 129 of Wayne Parsons’ individual contribution in Dudley (2000).


101<br />

policy analysts to built scientific knowledge on policy processes. In my case, discursive<br />

“frameworks” are to be understood as categorizations that explain fundamental,<br />

structural differences in people’s approaches to policy-making and planning.<br />

3.4.4 Discursive Frameworks versus Epistemic Communities<br />

There is yet another EU-focused strand of the political science literature whose<br />

relationship to my theoretical approach needs to be clarified. My argument that EU<br />

decision-making is dominated by the “discursive framework of ecological<br />

modernization” could seem to imply to some scholars that there is a simply dominant<br />

intellectual community of policy- and decision-makers in Brussels who operate both from<br />

within and outside the European Commission and who share common beliefs and<br />

worldviews. 18<br />

In considering recent political science writings by Haas (1992) as well as<br />

other U.S. (Miller and Fox 2001) and European-based writers (e.g. Radaelli 1999; Toke<br />

1999; Dunlop 2000; Zito 2001), one could therefore be tempted to argue that<br />

Commission employees, EU policy advisers, environmental advocates and lobbyists,<br />

together with scientists from various disciplines, simply form part of different “epistemic<br />

communities,” where the dominant community shares the discursive framework of<br />

ecological modernization, and others adhere to other discursive frameworks. Haas’<br />

18 Note that the frequent distinction between “academics” and “practitioners” is particularly blurry in the<br />

context of the European Commission and the stakeholders surrounding EU decision-making. Commission<br />

employees are highly trained staff coming from all over Europe, usually holding at least one Masters<br />

degree from a major European or U.S. university, and very frequently holding a doctorate as well. Almost<br />

all of them therefore have been socialized within academia, most of them in legal and economic disciplines.<br />

Commission staff are further engaged in an ongoing dialogue with the academic community. The majority<br />

of senior-level employees continues to publish in academic journals and presents papers at international<br />

conferences, and many of them hold academic positions before, during or after their time of employment at<br />

the Commission.


102<br />

(1992:3) comprehensive definition of the concept of epistemic communities, presented in<br />

the 1992 special issue of International Organization, is worth quoting in full here:<br />

An epistemic community is a network of professionals with recognized expertise and<br />

competence in a particular domain and an authoritative claim to policy-relevant<br />

knowledge within that domain or issue-area. Although an epistemic community may<br />

consist of professionals from a variety of disciplines and backgrounds, they have (1) a<br />

shared set of normative and principled beliefs, which provide a value-based rationale<br />

for the social action of community members; (2) shared causal beliefs, which are<br />

derived from their analysis of practices leading or contributing to a central set of<br />

problems in their domain and which then serve as the basis for elucidating the<br />

multiple linkages between possible policy actions and desired outcomes; (3) shared<br />

notions of validity – that is, intersubjective, internally defined criteria for weighing<br />

and validating knowledge in the domain of their expertise; and (4) a common policy<br />

enterprise – that is, a set of common practices associated with a set of problems to<br />

which their professional competence is directed, presumably out of the conviction that<br />

human welfare will be enhanced as a consequences.<br />

In developing the notion of discursive frameworks, however, I am in fact taking a<br />

very different, almost opposite approach from Haas and his colleagues. Contrary to<br />

political scientists who focus on tracing the influence of these so-called “epistemic<br />

communities”, my framework analysis focuses on the structural rationales underlying<br />

material decisions. Later chapters of my study then identify particular stakeholders (such<br />

as the European Round Table of Industrialists) who have influenced Commission<br />

thinking on infrastructure issues, yet these have done so not so much – as is expected<br />

from epistemic communities – through consensual means or impeccable rational<br />

argumentation but rather through concrete political and material forms of influence. I<br />

also argue that it is precisely the lack of a consistent policy approach which defines<br />

Community policy-making in the area of transport. For example, the Directorate General<br />

for Transport and Energy is most certainly home to somewhat different norms, causal


103<br />

beliefs, notions of validity and policy practices that the Directorate General for<br />

Environment, and both of them are in turn different from the Enlargement Directorate. 19<br />

In the end, the concept of epistemic communities remains inchoate and lacks<br />

rigorous empirical testing, most likely due to the methodological challenge of<br />

operationalizing it, i.e. of identifying, and gaining access to those suspected to be<br />

members of an epistemic community (Dunlop 2000). Also, the concept itself was<br />

developed in the context of a strand of political science (neo-functionalism) that tends to<br />

be overly idealistic about the possibilities of swaying European policy-makers away from<br />

short-term interest calculation by means of developing benign “knowledge” and<br />

“ideas.” 20 Haas’ conceptualization has further been accused of being overly positivistic,<br />

particularly in his portrayal of epistemic communities as being superior stakeholders to<br />

social movements due to their shared belief systems and knowledge bases (Toke 1999).<br />

The most debated, ultimately unresolved, question in the literature remains the relation of<br />

epistemic communities to other policy actors.<br />

Together, this explains why my subsequent analysis of EU decision-making does<br />

not make any further reference to the (rapidly growing) literature on epistemic<br />

19 In response, defendants of the “epistemic communities” approach could still argue that it is then possible<br />

to identify several different communities housed under the common roof of the Commission of the<br />

European Communities. This is a possible but increasingly far-fetched argument, especially since even the<br />

pertaining literature typically sees epistemic communities as acting mostly from outside the Commission<br />

(for a contrasting account, see Drake and Nicolaidis 1992; e.g. Peterson and Bomberg 1999; Radaelli<br />

1999). It is interesting to note that based on such an interpretation of multiple epistemic communities<br />

influencing EU policy-making, Zito (2001) shows how an epistemic community gathered around the (ecomodernist)<br />

principle of “critical loads” influenced EU policy on acid rain. Zito also introduces a simpler<br />

definition of an epistemic community as “a network of professionals sharing a common worldview” (p.<br />

588).<br />

20 Neofunctionalism is the most influential of the “classical” theories of European integration. Developed<br />

initially by Ernst Haas and others in the 1950s and 1960s, early account particularly focused on the selfreinforcing<br />

tendencies of integration, often emphasizing the importance of a technocratic consensus (see<br />

e.g. Haas 1958; Haas 1968; Pentland 1973 esp Ch 4). For a recent textbook article see Cram (1996), for a<br />

critique see Moravcsik (1998, especially 13ff).


104<br />

communities and related concepts. 21<br />

In my view, the major failing of the epistemic<br />

communities literature is that epistemic communities are envisioned to be rational actors<br />

limiting themselves to persuasion and foregoing other means of influence. As Zito<br />

(2001:588) has it: “The epistemic community should persuade EU actors to conform to<br />

its consensual (i.e. intersubjectively constructed) ideas without recourse to more material<br />

form of power.” By contrast, my case study of EU transport decision-making finds<br />

power and material practices to be much more influential than rational arguments in<br />

many instances. Put somewhat differently: My argument is based on the insight that<br />

ideas are shaped by power, and that “power defines reality” (Flyvbjerg 1998).<br />

21 A more realist concept that is also used by neo-functionalists is “entrepreneurship.” An entrepreneur is<br />

defined as “an actor or organization that advocates a policy and invests resources in promoting a position in<br />

return for some benefit” (Kingdon 1984, as quoted in Zito 2001:586). Consequently, entrepreneurship<br />

scholars are concerned with agenda-setting, support building, and deal brokering. According to the neofunctionalist<br />

strand of this literature, the Commission itself is an entrepreneur who has influenced and<br />

actively advanced European Integration (Sandholz and Zysman 1989; Cram 1997).


105<br />

Printed Thursday, October 31, 2002<br />

CHAPTER 4<br />

Ecological Modernization & Its Alternatives:<br />

Five Discursive Frameworks for Sustainable<br />

EU Transport Policy Making<br />

.<br />

4.1 Introduction..................................................................................................... 106<br />

4.2 Ecological Modernization: The Dominant Discursive Framework ................ 109<br />

4.2.1 Introducing the Framework..................................................................... 109<br />

4.2.2 Ecological Modernization and Sustainable Development ...................... 114<br />

4.2.3 Ecological Modernization as a Framework for EU Transport Policy..... 117<br />

4.3 Reflexive Modernization ................................................................................ 123<br />

4.3.1 Introducing the Framework..................................................................... 123<br />

4.3.2 Reflexive (Auto)mobility as a Framework for EU Transport Policy ..... 130<br />

4.4 Communicative Rationality ............................................................................ 136<br />

4.4.1 Introducing the Framework..................................................................... 136<br />

4.4.2 Communicative Rationality as a Framework for EU Transport Policy.. 141<br />

4.5 Political Economy........................................................................................... 146<br />

4.5.1 Introducing the Framework..................................................................... 146<br />

4.5.2 Political Economy as a Framework for EU Transport Policy................. 149<br />

4.6 Renunciation ................................................................................................... 159<br />

4.6.1 Introducing the Framework..................................................................... 159<br />

4.6.2 Renunciation as a Framework for EU Transport Policy......................... 166<br />

4.7 Addendum: The “Institutionalist” Focus on EU Space and Governance ....... 170<br />

4.8 Concluding Remarks....................................................................................... 173


106<br />

4.1 Introduction<br />

In the previous chapter, I defined a “discursive framework” as a theoretical<br />

approach consisting of an ensemble of underlying rationales and concepts that together<br />

form the intellectual backdrop for a set of policy responses and actions relating to a<br />

particular topic. Table 3.1 already provided an overview of the five identified discursive<br />

frameworks for sustainable policy-making, summarizing their overarching themes, their<br />

main unit of analysis and their main relevance for policy action. In this chapter, I<br />

elaborate on these five identified discursive frameworks and show how they are relevant<br />

for transport planning and policy-making in Europe. The explicit aim here is to not only<br />

elaborate on the dominant discursive framework of the European Union (and particularly<br />

of its Commission), namely ecological modernization, but to instead also make an effort<br />

to better contextualize this framework by clearly delineating it from complementary and<br />

alternative discursive frameworks which also make important contributions to the<br />

ongoing interdisciplinary debates on sustainability and sustainable development, both at<br />

the academic and at the professional level. Put in very simple terms, much of the<br />

disagreement between EU Commission staff at the Transport Directorate and sustainable<br />

transport advocacy NGOs over investment preferences, for example, can be explained by<br />

the fact that the two stakeholder groups operate within two fundamentally different<br />

discursive frameworks. One emphasizes growth, while the other stresses environmental<br />

sustainability and equity.<br />

While my typology of discursive frameworks is unlikely to present exhaustive<br />

coverage of the full range and diversity of writings on the subject of sustainable<br />

(transport) planning and policy-making, it nevertheless aims to categorize major trends


107<br />

and capture the most important strands of argumentation. Needless to say, the following<br />

categorizations are ideal-typical distinctions, and most researchers, policy-makers and<br />

activists do not necessarily fit neatly into one of the categories. The environmental<br />

movement, for example, is particularly torn between different strategies, with an<br />

increasing tendency to adhere to more mainstream (i.e. ecological or reflexive<br />

modernization) strategies in recent years (cf. Mol 2000, also see discussions below).<br />

Each section in this chapter begins with a general description of the approach,<br />

followed by an analysis of its more transport-specific elements drawing mainly from<br />

academic literature and, where appropriate, selectively from NGO policy statements. I<br />

also identify the key adherents to each approach. Chapter 5 will then review the most<br />

important EU policy statements in the area of sustainable development and transport in<br />

order to show the EU’s overall bias towards the discursive framework of ecological<br />

modernization.


108<br />

Table 4.1 Five Discursive Frameworks for Transport Planning and Policy-Making<br />

Theoretical<br />

Approach<br />

Key concepts<br />

Typical Transport<br />

Policy Proposals<br />

Key Proponents<br />

Ecological<br />

Modernization<br />

Competition<br />

Comparative<br />

Advantage<br />

Efficiency<br />

High-Technology<br />

Expand Networks<br />

Favor High Speed transport<br />

Low Emission Vehicles<br />

Polluter Pays<br />

Managed Growth<br />

EU & International<br />

Organizations<br />

Governments<br />

Business/Industry<br />

Mainstream NGOS<br />

Reflexive<br />

Modernization<br />

Risk<br />

Unintended<br />

consequences<br />

Expert Systems<br />

Democracy<br />

Precautionary principle<br />

(account for future impacts)<br />

Individuals “self-monitor”<br />

mobility (e.g. car sharing)<br />

Pricing Policies<br />

Transport<br />

Sociologists<br />

Some practitioners<br />

Some environmental<br />

NGOs<br />

Communicative<br />

Rationality<br />

Argumentation<br />

Legitimacy<br />

Discourse & Rhetoric<br />

Rationality<br />

No preference on proposals,<br />

focus on “rational” process<br />

& more participation in<br />

transport decision-making<br />

Equal access to information<br />

Mostly Academic<br />

(Planning theorists)<br />

Some practitioners<br />

Political<br />

Economy<br />

Redistribution<br />

Power Struggle<br />

Who benefits?<br />

Core vs. Periphery<br />

Subsidize public transport<br />

Make services affordable<br />

Charge Luxury taxes<br />

Socialist Politicians<br />

Civic NGOs<br />

Environmental<br />

Justice NGOs<br />

Renunciation<br />

Ecology<br />

Externalities<br />

Habitats<br />

Carrying Capacities<br />

Non-motorized transport<br />

Less long distance travel<br />

Less land use consumption<br />

Decrease overall mobility<br />

Deep Ecologists<br />

Some Green<br />

Politicians<br />

Conservationist<br />

NGOs<br />

Source: Own compilation


109<br />

4.2 Ecological Modernization: The Dominant Discursive Framework 1<br />

To the extent that sustainable development has come to have meaning, it has …<br />

primarily served as a vehicle for a form of ‘eco-managerialism’. In its most<br />

sophisticated form it has facilitated elements of what has been called ‘ecological<br />

modernization.’<br />

Frank Fischer and Maarten Hajer (1999:3)<br />

4.2.1 Introducing the Framework<br />

It is to the analysis of the concept of ecological modernization and its relationship<br />

with concept of sustainable development that we now turn. 2<br />

The overarching theme of<br />

the discursive framework of ecological modernization is “sustainable” growth, the key<br />

unit of analysis is the (market) economy and the related policy suggestions are those of<br />

pro-active, competitive action.<br />

Speaking simplistically, the concept of “ecological modernization” is really no<br />

more than an “efficiency-oriented approach to the environment” (Hajer 1995:101). Some<br />

see in it no more than a “neo-liberal environmentalism that is friendly to capitalist<br />

development” (Harper 2001:101). In my view, this is an overly simplistic, and partially<br />

1 In this study, I purposely do not distinguish between a “standard” modernization and an ecological<br />

modernization perspective. No serious scholar today would deny that environmental concerns are relevant<br />

and important for any kind of decision-making. So in my (as well as Hajer’s and other scholars’) view,<br />

ecological modernization rhetoric now is the standard development rhetoric (at least in Europe) to the point<br />

where it only makes sense to identify different levels of environmental commitment within the dominant<br />

perspective of ecological modernization. David Harvey (1996:373-383), by contrast, still (rather<br />

artificially) differentiates between a “standard view of environmental management” and ecological<br />

modernization. Yet even he himself is forced to admit that in this attempt to portray the general<br />

characteristics of ecological modernization, he is “exaggerating both its coherence and its difference from<br />

the standard view” (p.380).<br />

2 Eco-managerialism can be seen as a sub-concept of ecological modernization and it is therefore not<br />

specifically discussed in this study. Broadly defined, it focuses on the management of natural resources,<br />

risks and recreation (also see Luke 1999).


110<br />

incorrect view. Another, more useful definition of ecological modernization, at the same<br />

time relating it to the concept of sustainability, is provided by David Harvey (1996:377): 3<br />

Ecological modernization depends upon and promotes a belief that economic activity<br />

systematically produces environmental harm … and that society should therefore<br />

adopt a proactive stance with respect to environmental regulation and ecological<br />

controls. Prevention is regarded as preferable to cure. … The key word in this<br />

formulation is “sustainability.” And even though there are multiple definitions of<br />

what this might mean … the concept nevertheless lies at the heart of the politics of<br />

ecological modernization.<br />

It is useful to distinguish between an analytical and a prescriptive dimension of<br />

the term ecological modernization (Murphy 2000). By now, ecological modernization is<br />

both an academic theory and a political program. This is easily explained by the history<br />

of the concept, which Murphy aptly summarizes as follows (p.1):<br />

During the 1980s and early 1990s ecological modernisation was discussed and<br />

developed by a relatively small group of environmental social scientists, particularly<br />

within politics and sociology. From here, interest spread to other disciplines, such as<br />

geography, whilst the sphere of influence expanded away from Germany to the<br />

Netherlands, the UK and the USA. The growth of academic interest in ecological<br />

modernization is such that it is now becoming part of mainstream debate in the<br />

environmental social sciences.<br />

Note, however, that this chapter is not limited to a discussion of the function of<br />

ecological modernization as an academic theory or its function as a political program.<br />

Instead, my interpretation of the concept is more inspired by Maarten Hajer’s work.<br />

Hajer was mostly interested in ecological modernization as a particular environmental<br />

discourse that came to the fore in the 1980s. More precisely, Hajer has defined ecological<br />

3 Note that David Harvey’s understanding of the concept of ecological modernization was very much<br />

shaped and influenced by Maarten Hajer. Chapter 13 “The Environment of Justice” in Harvey’s 1996 book<br />

Justice, Nature and the Geography of Difference is the same as his chapters in the edited volumes The<br />

Urbanization of Injustice by Andy Merrifield and Erik Swyngedouw (1997) and Living with Nature by<br />

Frank Fisher and Maarten Hajer (1999). In the Merrifield and Swyngedouw volume Harvey adds the<br />

following enlightening acknowledgement at the end of his chapter, missing in both the JNGD chapter and<br />

the Fisher and Hajer volume:<br />

Much of this chapter could not have been written without the stimulus of supervising Maarten Hajer’s<br />

doctoral dissertation work in Oxford. That dissertation is now published under the title: The Politics of<br />

Environmental Discourse: Ecological Modernization and the Policy Process.


111<br />

modernization as “the discourse that recognizes the structural character of the<br />

environmental problematique but none the less assumes that existing political, economic,<br />

and social institutions can internalize the care for the environment” (Hajer 1995:25). It is<br />

thus defined as an approach that does not necessarily challenge status quo (power)<br />

arrangements in society and politics. It is therefore very appealing to policy-makers.<br />

The term ecological modernization was originally developed in the early 1980s in<br />

Germany by two political scientists, Joseph Huber and Martin Jänicke. They used the<br />

original German term ökologische Modernisierung to connote a more preventive,<br />

foresighted type of environmental policy that relied heavily on the precautionary<br />

principle (Vorsorgeprinzip) and had a long-term perspective. This is to be seen in<br />

contrast to the more end-of-pipe approaches of earlier periods that relied mostly on<br />

pollution control. Its core message is fundamentally optimistic, implying that better<br />

environmental protection ultimately improves economic efficiency in the long run.<br />

Within the framework of ecological modernization, growth and environmental protection<br />

are no longer antithetical, but complementary. Efficiency and ecology are almost treated<br />

as synonymous. In the words of Martin Jänicke (1988:23): “The strategy of ecological<br />

modernization aims at the same time for the improvement of ecological and economic<br />

efficiency.” Huber introduced the term “super-industrialization” to connote the idea that<br />

“the dirty and ugly industrial caterpillar will transform into an ecological butterfly”<br />

(Huber 1985:20 as quoted in Mol 1995:37). This frequently quoted sentence (see e.g.<br />

Murphy 2000:2; and Cohen 2001:3) has been become a central metaphor of ecological<br />

modernization.


112<br />

Although often misinterpreted as a free market ideology, from its beginnings the<br />

concept was also based on a political vision relying on active government intervention<br />

within a social market economy, as well as on state subsidies for research and<br />

development (see Murphy 2000:1). It therefore also has been called “a kind of green<br />

Keynesianism” (Boehmer-Christiansen 1994, quoted in Massa and Andersen 2000b:339).<br />

Not surprisingly, social democratic and green politicians across Europe are often strong<br />

proponents of the approach.<br />

Ecological modernization relies heavily on business and industry to develop<br />

cleaner and integrated technologies that are more resource efficient and less polluting. 4<br />

The European Union initiatives such as the Auto-Oil and Clean Air For Europe (CAFE)<br />

programs or the Automotive Fuel Quality Directive (98/70) are prime examples of this<br />

approach. Industrial development is seen as possibly in harmony with ecological<br />

development. Not surprisingly, Joseph Huber, one of the founders of the concept, has<br />

now become an active proponent of the somewhat newer term industrial ecology. 5<br />

Employing biologically imbued rhetoric, Huber (2000:269) hereby basically attempts to<br />

give the core concept of the original term of ecological modernization a new name:<br />

Industrial ecology aims at an industrial metabolism that is consistent with nature’s<br />

metabolism. The transformation of traditional industrial structures, which are often<br />

environmentally unadapted [sic] to an ecologically modernized consistent industrial<br />

4 The various billion Euro, multi-year EU research programs are a perfect testimony to the idea that<br />

sustainability research should receive government support. Also note that the proponents of the famous<br />

Factor 4 or Factor 10 approaches or of other eco-efficiency and eco-intelligence approaches typically<br />

associated with Green Party politics also tend to self-describe their suggestions as “ecological<br />

modernization.” However, several eco-efficiency scholars such as Erich von Weizsäcker or Wolfgang<br />

Sachs also clearly reject current growth-oriented strategies and related expansionary infrastructure schemes,<br />

and thus partially belong in the renunciation framework.<br />

5 Industrial ecology, like its predecessor ecological modernization, is now quickly becoming not only a new<br />

academic catchword, but also a new academic discipline. See, for example, the new home page of the<br />

International Society for Industrial Ecology (ISIE) hosted at the Yale School of Forestry and<br />

Environmental Studies (http://www.yale.edu/is4ie/). The Society held its inaugural meeting in Leiden, The<br />

Netherlands, in November 2001. I interpret industrial ecology here as yet another a sub-concept of<br />

ecological modernization.


113<br />

metabolism, implies major or basic technological innovations, as being different from<br />

incremental efficiency increasing change.<br />

Part of the reason that its original promoters presently apparently attempt to<br />

rescue the concept for themselves by means of the use of a new term is that the term<br />

“ecological modernization” has since undergone constant refinement and reinterpretation.<br />

Most importantly, although it would be incorrect to speak of an ecological<br />

modernization theory per se (also see Buttel 2000), the overall concept of ecological<br />

modernization has nevertheless become the dominant discourse in mainstream<br />

environmental policy-making. Researchers have differentiated between “weak” and<br />

“strong” versions of the concept (Christoff 1996).<br />

Nevertheless, most view it as a<br />

coherent view and attach high hopes to it. Massa and Andersen (2000a) even quote<br />

Giddens (1998:57-58) as remarking that “there is no doubt that ecological modernisation<br />

links social, democratic and ecological concerns more closely than once seemed<br />

possible.” 6<br />

Taking a more historical approach, Hajer (1995:94-96) provides four main<br />

reasons for the rise of ecological modernization in the 1980s: 1) the economic recession<br />

of the late 1970s where environmental issues began to lose out against concerns over<br />

inflation and mass unemployment, 2) changes within the environmental movement<br />

including professionalization and a restructuring among NGO elites, 3) the emergence of<br />

environmental problems such as acid rain or the greenhouse effect, which he interprets as<br />

6 Albert Weale (1992), however, maintains that it is an incoherent and ultimately ill-formulated ideology<br />

that often has to operate in rather different contexts. In his study, he compares British and German<br />

approaches to acid rain, finding that only in the German case did there develop a synthesis between<br />

adherents of the ‘clean air’ and the ‘economic feasibility’ coalitions. Maarten Hajer’s later study on The<br />

Politics of Environmental Discourse also focuses on the issue of acid rain, this time comparing acid rain<br />

campaigning in Britain and the Netherlands.


114<br />

being ‘less politically illuminating’ than nuclear power issues, and 4) the fact that an<br />

alternative, solution-oriented discourse was available.<br />

Finally, there is some disagreement in the literature over whether or not<br />

ecological modernization constitutes a new era within modernity or not. As interpreted in<br />

this study, it is decidedly not a radical concept, but precisely the one that allows for a<br />

continuation of current consumption and production schemes within capitalist<br />

democracies. That is, it is seen in contrast to a radical ecological or otherwise<br />

revolutionary concept aiming at a fundamental restructuring of present economic and<br />

political conditions. This is more in line with the interpretations of Hajer, Dryzek (see<br />

below) and others. 7<br />

4.2.2 Ecological Modernization and Sustainable Development<br />

At this point, it is also necessary to briefly clarify the relationship between the<br />

concepts of “ecological modernization” and “sustainable development”. Several scholars<br />

posit ecological modernization as an alternative to sustainable development, thus<br />

7 However, this is somewhat at odds with the interpretation that Mol and Spaargaren (1993) provide. Mol<br />

and Spaargaren distinguish two aspects of the concept, namely ecological modernization as a theory and as<br />

a political program (also see Seippel 2000:290). In its latter dimension, ecological modernization is seen<br />

as part of a three-part historical process in which environmentalism moves from a “counter-ideology” or<br />

“detraditionalization” towards “ecological modernization”, which is then to be succeeded by reflexive<br />

modernization. In linking perspectives on environmentalism with the concept of reflexive modernity, a<br />

concept most prominently developed by Ulrich Beck and Anthony Giddens, Mol and Spaargaren assert the<br />

existence of a distinctive change within modernity. It should be noted, however, that this interpretation is to<br />

be seen as distinct from Giddens’ argument regarding reflexive modernity. Giddens interprets reflexivity as<br />

an inherent characteristic of modernity throughout its history, and not as an only recently acquired<br />

additional quality (Giddens 1990). Also see below. To Mol and Spaargaren, the fact that ecological<br />

modernization is becoming institutionalized within the economic sphere is a key factor. In a later attempt<br />

to clarify the central elements of ecological modernization (not so much as a theory but as an historically<br />

distinct, political program), Mol (1995) proposes several, ultimately rather circular criteria: On one hand,<br />

changing roles are assigned to the nation-state, to market actors (both businesses and consumers), to<br />

science and technology, and to environmental NGOs. (The latter also change their overall ideologies).<br />

Finally, this is supposedly complemented by the emergence of a new environmental discourse (which<br />

brings us right back to the need to identify the elements of said new discourse).


115<br />

defining it as one of two theories for environmental policy-making in industrialized<br />

countries (Langhelle 2000). Their distinction is that while both theories ultimately<br />

assume that there is a postive-sum game between the environment and the economy,<br />

ecological modernization is supposedly more explicit about the assumed<br />

complementarity of the two. However, in such interpretations, ecological modernization,<br />

like sustainable development, remains a political and ideological concept and is not<br />

viewed as a distinct discursive framework (Berger, Flynn et al. 2001). As noted above, in<br />

this study, ecological modernization is identified as the key theoretical framework that,<br />

consciously or unconsciously depending on who uses it, has guided European<br />

environmental policy-making since the late 1980s.<br />

In this sense, sustainable<br />

development is a frequently used discursive concept used within the framework of<br />

ecological modernization, but it does not constitute an alternative framework in and of<br />

itself. In fact, the key point I want to make is that various sustainability discourses are<br />

being used within all of the discursive frameworks, but that the term “sustainable<br />

development” has ultimately been most successfully appropriated and re-interpreted by<br />

the mainstream proponents of ecological modernization. This distinction becomes more<br />

confused when researchers such as Mol and Spaargaren insist that ecological<br />

modernization itself is as much a distinct political program as it is a theoretical<br />

framework. 8<br />

Whenever it comes to political rhetoric, it is still almost always the concept<br />

of “sustainable development,” and not the more awkward-sounding term “ecological<br />

8 Ecological modernization does, however, have political implications. We can certainly identify distinct, or<br />

typical, policies and political programs that are the result of an adherence to the ecological modernization<br />

framework. This different from claiming that ecological modernization itself is mainly a political program.


116<br />

modernization” that is invoked by decision-makers. 9<br />

Few non-academics outside of<br />

Europe have even heard of ecological modernization as a distinct concept, whereas most<br />

high-school graduates will recognize the term “sustainable development” and even have a<br />

vague idea that it is “somehow related to environmental policy.”<br />

Since many researchers conflate or contrast the two terms in ways quite different<br />

from mine, their contributions deserve a quick analysis. In 2000, Langhelle wrote a<br />

longish article aimed at clarifying the relationship between ecological modernization and<br />

sustainable development. He makes a valuable contribution when he initially compares<br />

the two concepts and finds, most importantly, that “sustainable development is not only<br />

about the environment” and that the WCED and the Brundtland report were “first and<br />

foremost an attempt to reconcile the tension between developmental and environmental<br />

concerns at the global level” (p.308). To him, ecological modernization, on the other<br />

hand, “has no established relationship either to the global environmental problems or to<br />

social justice” and “relates primarily to the experiences of western industrialized<br />

societies.” 10<br />

It is thus an “OECD-centric” concept. Langhelle, borrowing from Jänicke<br />

(1997), also finds that “sustainable development seems to imply a larger degree of<br />

structural change.”<br />

Meanwhile, Dryzek (1997:143) understands “ecological modernization” and<br />

“sustainable development” as two different “sustainability discourses” and finds the key<br />

difference between the two is the frame of reference: He points out that ecological<br />

9 Ecological Modernization as a term for a political program, however, has gained more prominence among<br />

West European governments lately, and translations of the term are now actively used in governmental<br />

and/or party programs in Germany, Sweden, Finland and the Netherlands.<br />

10 Langhelle continues to point out several additional supposed differences between the two concepts, most<br />

of which I find much less relevant, e.g. that sustainable development goes further in acknowledging limits<br />

to growth and that it assumes greater ecological interdependence.


117<br />

modernization is about “what needs to be done with the capitalist political economy” so<br />

that it does not challenge the current world order, but it accepts and works within it.<br />

Dryzek is rather specific about the advantages of ecological modernization for business:<br />

since future cleanup is expensive, pollution prevention pays; moreover firms can make<br />

money by selling preventive devices and strategies as well as other green goods.<br />

Consequently, “the key to ecological modernization is that there is money in it for<br />

business” (Dryzek 1997:142), making it a pro-capitalist concept. By contrast, the<br />

concept of sustainable development provides both pro-capitalist and anti-capitalist<br />

interpretations, with a tendency towards the latter. This is consistent with my own<br />

interpretation of sustainable development as a term that is applied within different<br />

discursive frameworks. Note that ecological modernization is also defined as an<br />

exclusively pro-modern discursive framework, while sustainable development as a<br />

concept is also used by post-modernists and anti-modernists.<br />

4.2.3 Ecological Modernization as a Framework for EU Transport Policy<br />

Quite predictably, modernization-oriented transport economists and engineers<br />

stress the vital importance of efficient transport infrastructures for successful economic<br />

development, i.e. growth. They often narrowly equate sustainability with technological<br />

innovation and/or profitability. 11 In the modernization-oriented literature, technical and/or<br />

economistic solutions for road transport such as low-emission vehicles, smart cars,<br />

congestion pricing systems, or HOV lanes take precedence over a more fundamental<br />

11 To give a concrete example: during the 1999 World Bank Transport Expo, the ‘sustainability’ of toll<br />

roads was repeatedly defined as the ability of the private concession company to turn a profit.


118<br />

rethinking of transport systems, let alone of land use sustainability. 12 Yet most<br />

mainstream transport experts now at least verbally admit that there are “environmental<br />

limits to motorization.” There is also a growing recognition that the transport sector, and<br />

motorists in particular, impose costs on both society and nature that are not accounted for<br />

in present transport pricing mechanisms. In the last few years, a multitude of transportsector<br />

“social cost” or “externality” studies have been conducted for the US and Europe<br />

(see e.g. Greene, Jones et al. 1997; Hohnmeyer, Ottinger et al. 1997; Weinreich 1998;<br />

INFRAS/IWW 2000). Free parking has been identified as a major hidden subsidy to<br />

drivers in the US (Shoup 1997). Pressure on national governments for “getting the prices<br />

right” (T&E 1995) and for a more consistent application of the “polluter pays” principle<br />

is rising.<br />

At the same time, the macro-oriented debates over oil depletion, finite resources<br />

and the earth’s limited carrying capacities based on Malthusian insights of “Limits to<br />

Growth” (Meadows, Randers et al. 1972), or more recently, on the ideas of<br />

environmental economists like Daley or Constanza only inspired rather capital-intensive,<br />

innovation- and technology-based transport solutions which would fall in the “ecomanagerialism”<br />

category (Luke 1999). 13<br />

One striking example of this is that the<br />

international community’s main climate-change-combating financial instrument, the UN-<br />

12 For a particularly vehement argument that “the road transport system is almost always more efficient for<br />

the user than its competitors,” see Gerondeau (1997:pxxxvi). For a typical publication advocating electric<br />

vehicle use, try Sperling (1995). For a rather comprehensive and up-to-date overview of road and<br />

congestion pricing issues, pick up the edited volume by Button and Verhoef (1998).<br />

13 In the recent report “Toward a Sustainable Future” (TRB 1997:253ff) by the TRB Committee for the<br />

Study on Transportation and a Sustainable Environment in the US, STTP co-founder David Burwell issued<br />

a very interesting dissenting statement in the back of the report, carefully exposing the narrow, biological<br />

approach of this scientific committee. He clarifies that an analysis of environmental threats is not the same<br />

as a sustainability analysis, which would necessarily take a broader, systems view and include social<br />

measures of performance.


119<br />

and World Bank-funded Global Environmental Facility (GEF), was initially only going to<br />

fund transport projects related to alternative fuels and fuel cell technology. 14<br />

As the following chapter will confirm, most of official EU-speak is very close to<br />

the overall ideal of modernization and there is general agreement among scholars that the<br />

ideas of ecological modernization have directly influenced European Union policy<br />

making, particularly in the formulation of the influential 1993 White Paper on Growth,<br />

Competitiveness and Employment. More specifically, it was Jaques Delors himself and<br />

his think-tank Cellule de Prospective who picked up on the ideas of ecological<br />

modernization (also see Massa and Andersen 2000a; and Massa and Andersen 2000b).<br />

Tellingly, the White Paper also devoted a whole chapter to the TENs, “identifying them<br />

as a means of promoting growth and creating new jobs” (Williams 1996:168). The<br />

Commission itself then sold the ambitious TEN infrastructure plans with promises of<br />

huge economic savings, packaged in glossy brochures. To present one typical example:<br />

The EU could save transport users, and earn transport operators, a combined total of<br />

ECUs 138bn a year by 2005 in terms of money, time and reductions in other indirect<br />

costs like inflexibility. But such a big saving can only be reached if a whole building<br />

block of measures is carried out. (Commission of the European Communities<br />

1996b:131)<br />

Pro-construction optimism is not limited to Eurocrats, however. Gerondeau<br />

(1997) provides us with a recent example of a scholarly work defending the idea that<br />

“only the road can relieve the road” (p.xxxv). For him, European transport is<br />

increasingly dominated by road transport simply because “the road transport system is<br />

almost always more efficient for the user than its competitors” (p.xxxvi). Taking up all<br />

the major environmental and social problems associated with transport, such as<br />

14 Due to the intervention of sustainable transport advocacy groups, the emphasis has now been refocused.<br />

See www.ITDP.org.


120<br />

increasing congestion, air pollution, natural resource depletion, accidents and dominance<br />

of a road lobby, he concludes that critics distort the situation and that all these problem<br />

are solvable, preferably by building new, state-of-the art infrastructures. To him,<br />

modernization certainly means increasing automobilization, since “the car is an<br />

extraordinary key to freedom and quality of life.” His positivist belief in technical<br />

progress is unfailing:<br />

Of course, it would be absurd to deny the existence of harmful effects linked to the use<br />

of road vehicles. But in areas such as air pollution, they are now often grossly<br />

exaggerated. In fact, the problem is now being solved, as remarkable progress has<br />

been made by vehicle manufacturers.... Why should air quality be the only area where<br />

technological progress does not yield results?<br />

A similar attitude is apparent in the publication “Towards More Rational<br />

Transport Policies in Europe” by Achim Diekmann (1995:11):<br />

In a few years time, pollution by motor vehicles will have ceased to be a major<br />

problem and there will be sizeable cuts in fuel consumption as well. … Mobility must<br />

no longer be discriminated against. On the contrary, it has again to be seen as a<br />

positive, dynamic element in our society, as a provider of growth and welfare.<br />

It is typical for such positivist believers in technological progress to claim that<br />

their own views are non-ideological, and strictly based on “objective” evaluation of the<br />

facts. Excerpts from Gerondeau’s concluding paragraph reveal an interesting,<br />

“objectivizing” opinionatedness:<br />

There is then the risk that decisions are made based on ideological aphorisms. But<br />

ideology should have no place in transport policy. ... Means of transport are only tools.<br />

... The things that count are services rendered ... and the financial side of the issue, as<br />

one of the first duties of any public or private service is to not squander resources. ...<br />

It is a question of making the best possible decisions objectively and on the basis on<br />

facts and not opinions. ... All that really counts is the happiness of the people and the<br />

proper functioning of the economy, which is one of its conditions.<br />

(Gerondeau 1997 pp. 299-300, emphasis added)


121<br />

The automobile lobby, of course, takes the pro-car efficiency and modernization<br />

rhetoric to its most extreme. Diekmann’s book is a perfect example of the way in which<br />

this lobby appropriates the language of supposed scientific (read: market) rationality in<br />

order to argue for subsidy cuts in the rail sector and further deregulation of services. His<br />

concluding argument oscillates between economic rationality and ordinary polemic<br />

(pp.109-114):<br />

The primary objective of a rational transport policy is the optimal use of scarce<br />

resources and the protection and furthering of important economic and social goals.<br />

This objective requires reliance on market forces. It rules out subsidies.<br />

Environmental sustainability, which is one of the social goals, has to be pursued<br />

within this framework. … Instead of simply “milking” the road sector … increased reinvestment<br />

in improving and updating transport systems is required. … Maximising<br />

tax income from road transport is a permanent temptation for hard-pressed exchequers<br />

but the opposite of a rational long-term investment approach. [Among other things]<br />

governments should … press ahead the restructuring of railways in order to eliminate<br />

the huge subsidies they require, which have been the greatest stumbling block in<br />

making Europe’s transport system more efficient in the past.<br />

Together, Gerondeau and Diekmann exemplify a vision of modernization that<br />

does not really deserve the name “ecological.” For them, the environment is largely an<br />

obstacle to achieving modernization, growth and prosperity. Sustainability becomes a<br />

“social issue” (read: additional cost factor) and rail transport simply remains an<br />

“inefficient” mode. 15<br />

To be fair, there is of course a much more moderate strand of modernizationists<br />

who also tend to be economists rather than engineers. These scholars are less obsessed<br />

15 To some readers, it may seem unfair to base this sub-typification on highlights from quotes by only two<br />

select authors. However, Christian Gerondeau, a graduate of France’s prestigious Ecole Polytechnique,<br />

could hardly be regarded as “just any” independent, marginal, outside evaluator of European transport<br />

developments. During his distinguished 30-year civil service career at the highest levels of French public<br />

administration, Gerondeau played a significant role in shaping his country’s transport policies and plans,<br />

being personally responsible for several reform initiatives. Achim Diekmann is an economics professor at<br />

the university of Cologne. More importantly, Diekmann has been the director of the German Association<br />

of the Automobile Industry (Verband der Automobilindustrie e.V. - VDA) since 1968. He also held the<br />

position of chairman of the Liason Committee of the European Automobile Industry.


122<br />

with the expansion of road infrastructures than with the inefficiencies of all modes and<br />

networks. Very few of them are as dismissive of rail’s future as the car-oriented<br />

engineering and construction lobby. To these moderate modernizationists simple<br />

efficiency improvements in the physical transport infrastructures are futile unless they are<br />

complemented with other logistical, organizational and regulatory changes, especially<br />

where multiple national territories are transversed. The persistence of major transport<br />

bottlenecks at (former and still existing) national border crossings therefore emerges as<br />

another major concern. For example, Ratti (1995:71) identifies three major problems<br />

related to border crossings: 1) border barriers, in which real economic effects due to<br />

‘shipment ruptures’ can be observed, 2) border filters, characterized by the persistence of<br />

legal, fiscal and customs differences, and 3) border contact zones that are influenced by<br />

the heritage of old infrastructural situations as well as persistent institutional and cultural<br />

differences. These scholars also tend to focus on Trans-European Networks as providing<br />

the “missing links” necessary for proper European integration, but see them as a less<br />

exclusively physical problem. 16<br />

The resulting studies clearly emphasize the importance<br />

of national border crossings as a major impediment to efficient transport flows, and they<br />

tend to favor high-speed rail and combined transport infrastructures over road as the most<br />

appropriate modern transport solutions for Europe. The political weight this expert<br />

perspective has within the EU is demonstrated by the fact that of the 14 selected highpriority<br />

TEN transport projects, almost all involve high-speed rail or combined transport;<br />

only three are road-only projects and one is an airport. These “moderate<br />

modernizationists” would also never fail to mention the increasing importance of<br />

telecommunications and other technological solutions, while also recognizing the grave<br />

16 Chapter 6 presents a close examination of EU policy discourses on “bottlenecks” & “missing links”.


123<br />

external environmental and social costs of the transport sector. This more nuanced view<br />

is representative of a large number of recent works on transport and European integration<br />

funded by the NECTAR research group of the European Science Foundation (see<br />

especially the edited volumes by Nijkamp, Reichman et al. 1990; Banister and<br />

Berechman 1993; Nijkamp 1993; Banister, Capello et al. 1995; Coccossis and Nijkamp<br />

1995). Although these studies ultimately tend to concentrate on technological and<br />

logistical innovations as well as new, improved transport links as the keys to solving<br />

Europe’s transport problems, they nevertheless display a high degree of awareness of the<br />

comprehensive spatial, social and environmental issues involved. This particular network<br />

of scholars involved in the ESF’s transport research projects well represents current<br />

“mainstream” academic opinion with regard to Pan-European transport policy.<br />

4.3 Reflexive Modernization<br />

The social and the natural worlds today are thoroughly infused with reflexive human<br />

knowledge; but this does not lead to a situation in which collectively we are the<br />

masters of our destiny.<br />

Ulrich Beck, Anthony Giddens and Scott Lash (1994:vii)<br />

4.3.1 Introducing the Framework<br />

The concept of “risk rationality” has been immensely influential over the course of<br />

the last decade. One can even go as far as saying that in over the last decade, social<br />

scientists’ faith in modernity has been restored primarily through two concepts developed<br />

by the German sociologist Ulrich Beck: “reflexive modernization” and its subsidiary<br />

concept of the “risk society.” Note that there are important parallels in Beck’s work with


124<br />

the work of British sociologist Anthony Giddens. 17<br />

There is now even an emerging<br />

“sociology of (auto)mobility” and of “auto risk” that uses Beck’s work as a starting point<br />

(e.g. Beckmann 2001a, also see below).<br />

In distinction to ecological modernization, which is more economy-focused, reflexive<br />

modernization is thus a discursive framework that comes out of a sociological tradition<br />

and distinguishes itself through the overarching theme of “risk rationality”. The key<br />

policy relevance lies in the idea of precautionary action (also see below). Nevertheless,<br />

the discursive framework of reflexive modernity is quite complementary to ecological<br />

modernization. In fact, the term reflexive modernization is often discussed in conjunction<br />

with ecological modernization, with many scholars discussing the two as part and parcel<br />

of the same changing outlook on the future. This is particularly true of reflexive<br />

modernity’s overarching concern with risk. As David Harvey (1996:377) notes: “Beck’s<br />

(1992) formulation of the idea the we now live in a ‘risk society’ … has proven a useful<br />

and influential adjunct to the discursive thrust to define a risk-minimizing politics of<br />

ecological modernization.” In this study, I view reflexive modernity as an analytically<br />

distinct, albeit highly complementary discursive framework to ecological<br />

modernization. 18<br />

17 For a detailed outlook on the similarities and differences between the Beckian and the Giddensian<br />

conceptualizations of reflexive modernization/modernity, as well as the additional perspective of Scott<br />

Lash, see the insightful volume “Reflexive Modernization” co-authored by Beck, Giddens and Lash (1994).<br />

18 Remember that Mol and Spaargaren (1993), by contrast, present an evolutionary explanation that views<br />

reflexive modernization as the concept that will eventually supersede ecological modernization as a<br />

mainstream political program (also see above). Alternatively, Davoudi (2001b) views ecological<br />

modernization and the risk society as the two “twin discourses of sustainability” and credits the latter with<br />

seeing “irreconcilable conflict between the current mode of production and environment,” calling for<br />

“greater participation in policy-making … and social transformation” and presenting a “radical” and<br />

“moral” vision of sustainability. In essence, her “risk society” face can thus be seen as a conflation of my<br />

discursive frameworks of reflexive modernization, communicative rationality, and political economy.


125<br />

The Australian planning theorist Brandon Gleeson (2000:117ff) has made a<br />

pertinent argument that sociological theories of reflexive modernization, despite their<br />

limited consideration in fields such as urban, regional or transport planning at present, 19<br />

are in fact highly relevant to all spatial science, and to infrastructure decision-making.<br />

This can be taken as an indirect argument that this perspective is relevant for EU<br />

transport policy as well, and the concept indeed provides a useful framework within<br />

which “to place and understand the recent transformation of western urban and<br />

environmental planning systems.”<br />

The overall crisis of state legitimacy (see e.g. O'Connor 1973; Habermas 1976;<br />

Connolly 1984; Offe and Keane 1984) has haunted planners and policy-makers for<br />

decades now, challenging them to reevaluate their inherent reliance on “modernist”,<br />

hierarchical decision-making systems. Various green, feminist and otherwise progressive<br />

social movements have attempted to reclaim democracy by refocusing attention on grassroots<br />

activism and local politics. In this context, Gleeson (2000:118) claims that<br />

reflexive modernization offers at least a partial solution to the legitimation crisis by<br />

“suggesting a transformative politics that is at once historical and progressive … [and]<br />

demands the re-modernization of modernity, involving, inter alia, the replacement of the<br />

modernist state by a reflexive, cosmopolitan democracy.” How is it then, precisely, that<br />

theories of reflexive modernization offer solutions with regard to the desired reenlightening<br />

of planning and policy-making?<br />

A quick review of Beck’s work yields some interesting answers. A first step is<br />

the analytical separation of industrialism (and the related industrial society model) on the<br />

19 Some noteworthy exemptions are Gleeson’s own work (Gleeson 2000; Low and Gleeson 2001), Blowers<br />

(1997) and Beckmann (2001a).


126<br />

one hand, and modernization (and modernity more generally) on the other hand.<br />

Consequently, the political-economic and cultural changes brought about by the deindustrialization<br />

of Western societies should be seen not as an indication of a move<br />

towards post-modernity, but rather as a “break within modernity, which is freeing itself<br />

from the contours of the classical industrial society and forming a new form – the<br />

(industrial) risk society” (Beck 1992:9, also quoted in Gleeson 2000:119 with added<br />

emphases). Triggered by two deeply symbolic historical events – the 1984 Chernobyl<br />

disaster and the 1989 fall of the <strong>Berlin</strong> Wall 20 – Beck finds that previous, sciencefocused,<br />

linear, instrumental rationality is increasingly giving way to a new reflexive<br />

rationality in which nature and society are no longer objectified but assessed in a more<br />

self-aware manner. In this process, nature becomes highly politicized and social<br />

institutions radically recomposed. In essence, Beck explains the rise of environmental<br />

awareness and the emergence of new forms of (multi-level) governance as an outcome of<br />

the most evident failures of the industrial society model. Neither capitalist nor socialist<br />

attempts at industrial modernization were ultimately capable of producing the universally<br />

prosperous, just and nature-controlling societies that their various proponents promised.<br />

Nature is indeed increasingly disenchanted but never successfully dominated. What is<br />

more important is that, quite frequently, the negative side effects or unintended<br />

consequences related to the usage of modern technologies outweigh their benefits.<br />

The transport sector provides a perfect example of this dynamic. At present, the<br />

comfortable and speedy mobility afforded to large parts of the population in OECD<br />

countries by means of fossil fuel-dependent automobile and air transport is in large part<br />

20 These two events are, as Gleeson correctly notes in his own review of Beck, indeed very eurocentric<br />

choices.


127<br />

responsible for rising levels of carbon dioxide emissions. These emissions are in turn<br />

likely to alter the earth’s atmosphere to the point where an accelerated process of global<br />

warming negatively affects the entire world population, especially those living in coastal<br />

and otherwise ecologically-exposed regions. So far, governments have been rather<br />

unsuccessful in reversing this dynamic.<br />

The key insight Beck provides in his book Risk Society is that modern society has<br />

entered a development stage in which governments and other institutions are increasingly<br />

unable to adequately assess and monitor the social and environmental risks of industrial<br />

development (especially those embedded in the use of nuclear and biochemical<br />

technologies). Uncertainty and risk enter the equation. Technology and science are no<br />

longer unconditional guarantors of prosperity and progress.<br />

However, this does not mean that the modernist project needs to be rejected,<br />

since, as Beck as well as Giddens argue in later works, modernity is well capable of reevaluating<br />

and reinventing itself. The rise of “counter-modernizing” forces does not<br />

threaten modernity but strengthens it, resulting in a new stage of reflexive modernization<br />

in which a new dialectic of counter-modernization and modernization continually propels<br />

us forward, opening the way for other, perhaps yet more advanced “alternative<br />

modernities” (see e.g. Beck 1997). These could, in principle, be regressive – indicated,<br />

for example, by Augé’s (1995) ideas of the excessiveness of supermodernity or the rising<br />

concerns among scholars with regard to the resurgence of nationalist and ethnocentric<br />

movements. Beck’s hope, however, is for a “reinvention of politics” that addresses the<br />

problems of uncertainty and risk by re-integrating and reinstitutionalizing the core<br />

Enlightenment concept of doubt into modern policy-making. For Beck, “doubt … is the


128<br />

most certain victor of modernity” (p.166). To be sure, he is speaking of a doubt “arising<br />

not from ignorance but from greater knowledge and further questioning” i.e. a doubt<br />

arising out of a general attitude of self-awareness and even self-criticism.<br />

Gleeson (2000:124), inspired by contemporary defenders of Enlightenment<br />

thought such as Beck and Hayward and, ultimately, by Kant himself, joins their plea for<br />

“a non-reductionist view of the Enlightenment that avoids the simple depiction of<br />

modernization as the rule of instrumental rationality.” In particular, he correctly points to<br />

the misleading dichotomy apparent in much ecological thought opposing Nature and<br />

Enlightenment. Gleeson (132-133), however, ultimately ends up concluding his call for a<br />

re-enlightenment of planning and policy-making by simply suggesting the following:<br />

In the contemporary context, modernization implies a broad reanimation of urban<br />

governance that recognizes and addresses the demise of simple industrialism and the<br />

rise of a new reflexive modernity.… What Beck’s thesis suggests is that planning, and<br />

other democratic institutions, must project uncertainty into domains of ‘constructed<br />

certitude’, such as the market, and resist the pressures to surrender up critical<br />

awareness. The precautionary principle seems to recommend itself as a concrete<br />

instance of what Beck has in mind. Reading Beck, this principle represents perhaps<br />

one possible public interest for a re-enlightenment of planning. [Its] application to<br />

planning would help identify and regulate the ecological and social risks arising<br />

from the production of space. This is not to furnish an excuse for institutional<br />

procrastination, but a new remit for precautionary action authorized by democratic<br />

rather than simply scientific or economic opinion.<br />

[Bold emphasis added, italics in the original.]<br />

For Gleeson, as an urban theorist/planner, to inadvertently revert to this oldest,<br />

most original of all ecological modernization principles at the end of his reflections on<br />

reflexive modernization is highly revealing. The article is explicitly based on a review of<br />

Ulrich Beck’s work and makes no reference to the ecological modernization literature, so<br />

Gleeson does not mention the central role that the originators of ecological modernization<br />

theory, Jänicke and Huber, afforded to the Vorsorgeprinzip (i.e. the precautionary


129<br />

principle) for the development of their ecological modernization theories. Yet it appears<br />

as an almost Freudian slip for Gleeson to suggest that the suggested re-enlightenment of<br />

planning in essence consist of an improved identification and regulation (!) of “the<br />

ecological and social risks arising from the production of space.” By presenting such a<br />

limited vision, Gleeson holds planners (and policy makers) locked within the bounds of a<br />

crisis-managing ecological modernization approach that keeps them deeply implicated in<br />

the ongoing crisis of state legitimacy which he himself also bemoaned at the outset of his<br />

article (and which is now more fashionably discussed under the label “governance”). The<br />

actual “producers of space” in modern capitalist democracies (e.g. property developers,<br />

industrialists, construction companies, and, in some limited cases, the state itself), on the<br />

other hand, remain fundamentally unchallenged in their role, since their actions are at<br />

best being “regulated”. Planners are once again relegated to being the “henchmen” of<br />

capitalist market development. Foglesong’s (1986) capitalist-democracy contradiction<br />

remains unresolved. Finally, Gleeson’s suggestion that this precautionary action (i.e.<br />

regulation) be legitimated by “democratic rather than simply scientific or economic<br />

opinion” shows a welcome post-positivist awareness regarding the impossibility of<br />

scientific objectivity, but it also ends the discussion at the very point where it should<br />

begin, namely with a debate over how exactly democratic institutions would need to be<br />

re-conceptualized in order to successfully build critical awareness (and, equally important<br />

in my view, re-distributive mechanisms) into planning and political decision-making.<br />

Gleeson simply leaves us hanging, concluding with the insight that democracy, (defined<br />

here as “the refusal of humanity to be governed without reason”) is the central ideal of<br />

reflexive modernization.


130<br />

While it would be unfair to make Ulrich Beck responsible for the shortcomings in<br />

Gleeson’s conclusions (which, in my view, ultimately fail to successfully re-enlighten<br />

planning), Gleeson’s article is nevertheless highly indicative of a common problem of<br />

theoretical adaptations of reflexive modernization, namely that the theory, like ecological<br />

modernization, has a rather limited potential to induce (radical) political change. Even in<br />

the face of dramatic social and environmental threats and injustices, we are always to<br />

have faith in modernity’s (and modernity’s institutions’) capacity to re-invent itself. 21<br />

4.3.2 Reflexive (Auto)mobility as a Framework for EU Transport Policy<br />

The term reflexive auto(mobility) connotes the fact that scholars writing within<br />

the discursive framework of reflexive modernity increasingly consider automobility and<br />

modernity to be interwoven, mutually dependent concepts (Urry 1999; Kesselring 2001;<br />

Rammler 2001; Beckmann 2001a). In this new, emerging field of transport sociology,<br />

the private car is viewed as the central element shaping late modernity. These scholars<br />

show how the automobile symbolizes speed, acceleration, flexibility of movement,<br />

individualized mobility and protection from outside environmental influences. At the<br />

same time, they argue, highways, and in particular the North American parkways, were<br />

explicitly built to afford middle class car owners a pleasant drive though nature. And it is<br />

of course North America which has been most prominent in the development of<br />

21 It is thus not completely by chance that Beck’s British brother-in-arms in the popularization of reflexive<br />

modernization, Anthony Giddens, has been such a key influence on Tony Blair in the UK. Regardless of<br />

whether one considers the approach successful or not, it seems undisputable that Giddens’ and Blair’s<br />

“Third Way” reinterpretation of social-democratic politics as an approach “beyond left and right”<br />

thoroughly erased whatever radical potential the British Labor party had left.


131<br />

automobility as part and parcel of modern culture. 22<br />

Freeways are seen as connoting<br />

ultimate freedom. 23<br />

Sociologists writing on reflexive automobility are not prescriptive in their<br />

analyses. They claim to observe, rather than judge, developments, and thus seldom<br />

present policy recommendations. They recognize the fact that the environmental effects<br />

of automobility are highly problematic, but instead of focusing on the negative effects of<br />

motorization, they tend to focus on the social “causes” of automobilization (Beckmann<br />

2001:28). Automobility is interpreted as a “spatio-temporal phenomenon” (Beckmann<br />

2001) which is in turn related to the time-space compression characteristic of late<br />

modernity (see Giddens 1990 and Harvey 1989). John Urry (1999:1) finds that “the<br />

social and technical system of the car constitutes an enormously complex hybrid<br />

‘automobility’” and he develops a set of six components that together make up the<br />

“’specific character of domination’ that automobility exerts over almost all societies<br />

across the globe.” 24 It is a rather subtle type of domination, however, largely relying on<br />

the use of expert systems and knowledge. As Giddens (1990:28) notes:<br />

When I go out of the house and get into a car, I enter settings which are thoroughly<br />

permeated by expert knowledge – involving the design and construction of<br />

automobiles, highways, intersections, traffic lights, and many other items. … I have<br />

minimal knowledge about the technicalities of modes of road building, the<br />

maintaining of the road surfaces, or the computers which help control the movement<br />

of traffic.<br />

22 Think, for example, of Tom Waits’ songs, Jack Kerouac’s novel On the Road, or films such as Easy<br />

Rider, Bonnie and Clyde, Thelma and Louise, Paris, Texas. For an academic analysis of the road movie<br />

genre and its relationship to mobility, see Eyerman and Löfgren (1995).<br />

23 Urry (1999) uses Baudrillard’s America in order to elaborate on this as follows:<br />

American post-war landscapes are empty and stand for modernity and the rejection of the complex<br />

histories of European societies. This emptiness is a metaphor of the American dream. Baudrillard<br />

suggests that ‘America’ undertook to make utopia real, to realise everything through the strange destiny<br />

of simulation. Culture then in America is ‘space, speed, cinema, technology’ (Baudrillard 1988:100).<br />

24 The six components he discusses are manufactured object, individual consumption, machinic complex,<br />

quasi-private mobility, culture, and environmental resource-use.


132<br />

In short, the car, which is also commonly called private motorized transport, 25<br />

with its reliance on social and physical infrastructures, turns out to be far from being the<br />

perfectly individual means of transport that it purports to be (Beckmann 2001:45).<br />

As far as policy approaches related to the phenomenon of reflexive automobility<br />

are concerned, both scholars and practitioners working within the related discursive<br />

framework pointed to new individual user strategies and user typologies (see e.g. Jensen<br />

1999; Canzler 2000). Car sharing schemes are probably the most prominent practical<br />

example of this development. Interestingly, both Canzler and Beckmann find that the<br />

frequently evoked account of increasingly individualized transport strategies in light of<br />

the complex travel requirements in post-industrial societies in fact does not mean that the<br />

car necessarily has to be the most successful mode. Especially in urban areas, they argue,<br />

automobility has long reached its efficiency limits. In these urban contexts, greater<br />

individualization is likely to foster greater multimodality in the future. City dwellers<br />

might continue to use their cars for weekend trips, for retail shopping and for out-of<br />

town commutes, but if congestion and parking remain as problematic as they are at<br />

present, many of them will gladly travel to work by public transport, and if convenient<br />

and safe, possibly even ride to the transit station by bicycle.<br />

Examples of these developments are already visible in several EU member states,<br />

most prominently in the form of the integrated mobility services now offered by several<br />

railways companies. For example, the recently privatized German national railway<br />

25 The most common German acronym for car travel, for example, is “MIV”, which stands for “motorized<br />

individual transport (Verkehr).”


133<br />

company Deutsche Bahn is now offering car sharing and bike rental services as part of its<br />

company profile. 26<br />

According to transport sociologists, another distinguishing feature of reflexive<br />

automobility is that, in late modernity, the so-called “modern mobility paradigm” is<br />

supposedly shaped by an increasing number of players. Beckmann (2001:51ff), for<br />

example, argues that the exceptional power vested in the automotive industry and the<br />

government to equip the populace with automobiles and to provide a pertaining<br />

“modern”, i.e. functionally segregated and car-dominated transport system, is a thing of<br />

the past. Instead of the two “big players,” industry and government(al planners), the<br />

stage is now crowded with a host of additional “collective actors,” such as citizens’ and<br />

environmental groups (e.g. Friends of the Earth - FOE, Greenpeace, European Federation<br />

for Transport & Environment - T&E), rail associations (e.g. Community of European<br />

Railways – CER), car and bicycle clubs (European Cyclists Federation - ECF), road and<br />

industry lobby groups (European Road Federation, European Round Table of<br />

Industrialists), as well as research institutes and think tanks (Centre for European Policy<br />

Studies - CEPS). Interestingly, making a similar point as Mol (2000), Beckmann notes<br />

the loss of radical voices within the environmental movement.<br />

The network of actors within automobility also becomes denser and more tightly<br />

woven. It is the collaboration between the former “enemies” that reforms the network.<br />

Nowadays, car-manufacturers are working closely together with (ex-)grass-rootmovements<br />

such as car sharing clubs. The old animosity … seems to be over. The<br />

transformation of alternative clubs into established transport actors gains additional<br />

impetus with the professionalisation of their services. [p.52]. 27<br />

26<br />

See http://www.bahn.de/konzern/holding/db_rent/dbag_call_a_bike.shtml and http://www.bahn.de/<br />

konzern/ holding/db_rent/dbag_carsharing.shtml.<br />

27 Beckmann links this phenomenon back to Beck’s overarching theory of reflexive modernization by<br />

identifying the rise of these new institutions and organizations as an example of what Beck calls “the<br />

disintegration of institutional power” which is in turn part of the “subpoliticization of late modern<br />

societies”. Subpolitics is defined by Beck as a direct(er) form of politicking by means of “ad hoc<br />

individual participation in political decisions, by-passing the institutions of representative opinion-


134<br />

It is true that the resulting policy discourses are indeed more professional and at<br />

the same time largely de-radicalized and surprisingly consensual. Professionals and<br />

experts from the governmental and non-governmental sectors are now discoursing<br />

amongst themselves. Political differences of opinion remain relevant, but all actors take<br />

recourse in scientific research and expert conclusions to back their arguments. Note, for<br />

example the argumentation presented by the sustainable transport NGO T&E (2000:iii):<br />

A recent overview by a panel of leading experts in this field has concluded that<br />

there are in fact no automatic economic or employment benefits from [transport<br />

infrastructure investments]. The assumptions and prejudices held by Europe’s<br />

decision makers [with regard to the relationship between transport investments and<br />

regional economic development] are, in fact, incorrect.<br />

[Emphasis in the original.] 28<br />

Such continued reliance on scientific experts runs counter to Beckmann’s<br />

conclusion that decision-making is now significantly influenced by less privileged, nonexpert<br />

decision-makers. So we are not witnessing the rise of the lay experts or, as<br />

Beckmann calls them, “layperts” as additional stakeholders in environmental decisionmaking,<br />

as much as an increasing reliance on privileged (academic) expert knowledge for<br />

the solution of environmental problems. This is also congruent with Giddens’<br />

interpretation of reflexive modernity as being dominated by expert systems. The<br />

phenomenon is particularly apparent for discourses assessing the environmental risks<br />

inherent in current auto-dependent transport systems. 29<br />

formation (political parties, parliaments) and often lacking the protection of the law” (Beck 1992, as quoted<br />

in Beckmann 2001:54). This observation is also relevant for my analysis of Pan-European transport policy.<br />

28 For a more complete excerpt from this text, see the “cohesion” section of chapter 4 on transport policy<br />

storylines.<br />

29 Note that Giddens and Beck indeed provide different answers to the question of who the key medium of<br />

the reflexive modernization is. As Beck clarifies (1994:175): “Unlike Giddens [who emphasizes scientific<br />

expert knowledge], I assert the thesis … that it is not knowledge, but rather non-knowledge which is the<br />

key medium of ‘reflexive’ modernization. To put it in another way: we are living in an age of side effects.”


135<br />

In related studies, car accidents appear as an individualized risk which directly<br />

translates into a major social cost associated with this mode. The TERM reports<br />

published by the European Environmental Agency are a perfect example of such<br />

awareness-raising scientific “objective” reporting. Figure 4.1 shows a graph taken from<br />

the 2001 TERM report (European Environment Agency (EEA) 2001) that is clearly<br />

making the point that the risk of car accidents imposes exorbitant external costs on<br />

society. The credited sources are INFRAS and IWW, two major European research<br />

institutions which conducted an external cost study on behalf of the International Union<br />

of Railways. The resulting policy recommendation is without doubt a decreased<br />

dependence on individual car transport. This example illustrates how complex arguments<br />

related to the environmental impacts of transport are effectively short-circuited through<br />

the implicit assumption that standard cost benefit methodologies developed by major<br />

research institutions correctly and objectively capture environmental risks and costs<br />

associated with the different modes, even if the relevant research is clearly initiated and<br />

paid for by a stakeholder with a vested interest in demonstrating problems associated<br />

with car transport. 30<br />

In sum, society has become dependent on experts to quantify, assess<br />

and ultimately remedy the environmental and social risks associated with modern<br />

transport systems. This prospect is disempowering to laypersons who are often<br />

confronted with contrasting “scientific” assessments.<br />

30 Note that I personally do not think that the INFRAS/IWW assessments are politically biased. I<br />

nevertheless agree that it is important to point out that, in the end, all environmental cost calculations are of<br />

course socially constructed. What exact value we attach to qualities such as equal mobility rights, clean air,<br />

unservered landscapes and good public health is ultimately a matter of societal consensus-building and<br />

political argumentation. Economics remains a social science.


136<br />

Figure 4.1 Environmental Costs/Risks of Transport as presented by the EEA<br />

Source: EEA (2001)<br />

4.4 Communicative Rationality<br />

If there is one theme that runs through all the discussions and debates on planning, it<br />

is that of rationality.<br />

John Friedmann (1987:97)<br />

Power has a rationality that rationality does not know.<br />

Bent Flyvbjerg (1998:225)<br />

4.4.1 Introducing the Framework<br />

The overarching theme of the discursive framework of communicative rationality<br />

is simply rationality itself. The unit of analysis is not really society as a whole, but rather<br />

people and institutions. The relevance for policy lies in the elaboration of the concept of<br />

“communicative action.” “Communicative rationality” concepts have only rather<br />

recently been applied to the realm of transport policy and planning. As Richard Willson


137<br />

(2001:2) recently summarized: “Communicative rationality has not been reviewed in<br />

transportation journals; planning theory research seldom links to transportation<br />

planning.” Since, thanks to Willson and a few others, there is now an emerging literature<br />

on communicative rationality in transport planning, I decided to recognize it as a distinct<br />

and policy-relevant development approach for the specific area of European transport<br />

policy, even if there are currently no transport practitioners discernable at the EU level<br />

who consistently practice such an approach. Nevertheless, I argue that it is important to<br />

recognize “communicative rationality” as a distinct discursive framework with its own<br />

distinct policy preferences, regardless of whether or not these policy preferences are<br />

presently actualized or not. After all, since “ecological modernization” is so clearly the<br />

dominant approach to EU transport policy and planning, most of the policy preferences<br />

resulting from the other discursive frameworks are not being implemented at present<br />

either. Note that there are some parallels between the increased currency the concept of<br />

communicative rationality is gaining in planning and public policy circles and the current<br />

debate over the future of European Governance, which culminated in the publication of<br />

the EU’s White Paper on European Governance (also see Chapter 5).<br />

The term “communicative rationality” inevitably evokes the name of Jürgen<br />

Habermas. There is now an extensive literature entirely devoted to the elaboration of the<br />

concept of communicative rationality and its application to planning and public policy,<br />

variously presented under the label of communicative planning (Forester 1989; Sager<br />

1994), communicative action (Innes 1995), argumentative planning (Fischer and Forester<br />

1993), or collaborative planning / planning through debate (Healey 1992; Healey 1997).<br />

It has even been interpreted as the new dominant “paradigm” for the sub-field of planning


138<br />

theory (Innes 1995) and a potential one for transport planning (Willson 2001), although<br />

Muller (1998) and Taylor (1999) rightfully question the applicability of the term in this<br />

context. Willson (2001:2) states that “the global aim of communicative rationality is to<br />

create a rational basis for constructing ends and means in a democratic society, by<br />

enriching public and political discourse.” In pursuing this aim, however, the<br />

communicative approach is often selective in its application of Habermasian theory. At<br />

its core lies a notion of reason that is historically situated and created through intersubjective<br />

mutual understanding. Communicative theorists aim to establish knowledge<br />

claims through processes of argumentation that are interactively carried forward by a<br />

given set of people at a given time and place, thus creating a system that is not (or at least<br />

considerably less) dependent on validation from “experts” or other outside influences.<br />

Within these processes, planners are to become mediators among stakeholders, rather<br />

than stakeholders themselves. (Note that the respective role of a bureaucrat or policymaker<br />

is less clear). According to Healey (1997:29), the central tenets of the<br />

communicative model are its inherent social constructivist understanding of knowledge,<br />

its focus on social interaction, its openness towards alternative forms of knowledge and<br />

reasoning (e.g. storytelling, subjective statements), and finally, its call for public policy to<br />

constitute itself by drawing upon and making available a wide range of knowledge and<br />

reasoning from different sources. 31<br />

As an analytic method for studying planning and policy processes, the<br />

communicative rationality framework no doubt deserves credit for contributing many<br />

31 Note that although they are supposedly rooted in Habermasian discourse theory, i.e. a theory still<br />

working within the Enlightenment tradition, the tenets which Healy identifies are, of course, fully<br />

congruent with postmodern ideals of knowledge-seeking. Consequently, the “communicative turn” in<br />

planning is regarded by many primarily as a post-modernizing, rather than a re-modernizing trend.


139<br />

excellent, discourse- and rhetoric-focused micro-level case studies that are very useful for<br />

understanding how exactly decision-makers go about doing their work (e.g. Forester<br />

1989; Healey 1992; Throgmorton 1992; Healey and Hillier 1996). It is only when the<br />

analyses turn from critique to recommendation that the model runs into problems. Here,<br />

many communicative theorists display a tendency to be overly idealistic about preexisting<br />

power relationships, which are particularly relevant when dealing with large<br />

scale infrastructures (as is certainly the case with the EU TENs). Taken together, Susan<br />

Fainstein’s and Tim Richardson’s critiques present a concise summary of the model’s key<br />

deficiencies from a political economy perspective. Fainstein (2000:455) notes that<br />

in its effort to save planning from elitist tendencies, communicative planning theory<br />

runs into difficulties. … Although their roots, via Habermas, are in critical theory,<br />

once the communicative theorists move away from critique and present a manual for<br />

action, their thought loses its edge. Habermas posited the ideal speech situation as a<br />

criterion by which to register the distortion inherent in most interactions. … But when<br />

instead ideal speech becomes the objective of planning, the argument takes a<br />

moralistic tone, and its proponents seem to forget the economic and social forces that<br />

produce endemic social conflict and domination by the powerful. There is the<br />

assumption that if only people were reasonable, deep structural conflict would melt<br />

away. Although unquestionably many disagreements can be ameliorated through<br />

negotiation … persistent issues of displacement as a consequence of modernization<br />

and siting of unwanted facilities proximate to weak constituencies are less susceptible<br />

to resolution.<br />

And, one might add, as scores of local activist groups fighting unwanted<br />

motorways all over Europe will confirm, such “weak constituents” are often only able to<br />

make their voice heard if they are able to frame their opposition within solid<br />

environmental arguments, i.e. arguments backed by scientific evidence and couched in<br />

legalistic language that allows them to take their arguments to court. Consequently, as<br />

Richardson (2000:13) points out, communicative rationality theorists’


140<br />

analyses and prescriptions suffer a credibility gap. The analytical work focuses only<br />

on certain parts of planning activity – principally communicative exchanges – and the<br />

normative work relies on a leap of faith … which goes beyond the experience and<br />

convictions of many practicing planners.<br />

The discursive framework of communicative rationality also distinguishes itself<br />

through its assumption that people do not have fixed interests (see especially Healey<br />

1997) and that overarching power structures do not predetermine outcomes. 32 This is a<br />

recurring and ongoing point of contention that we will revisit especially when we discuss<br />

the importance of storylines in constituting and influencing policy processes.<br />

In terms of the key activist proponents, those elements of the communicative<br />

rationality discourse that point to increased participation and equal access to decisionmaking<br />

are frequently championed by environmental NGOs.<br />

Contrary to the<br />

communicative ideal, however, these are typically groups with inadequate access to<br />

dominant power structures. Their obvious claim is that they defend the interest of civil<br />

society and the environment against capitalist market interests and biased financial<br />

institutions and governments. Regardless of the necessity of such work and the validity<br />

of their claim, this certainly precludes any non-existence of fixed interests on the part of<br />

the NGOs. Environmental and civic NGOs are not as much interested in being<br />

moderators as monitors of planning and policy processes. A good example is the CEE<br />

Bankwatch Network, which has done several detailed case studies on EU transport<br />

32 Also note that different proponents of communicative action-inspired methodologies subscribe to this<br />

view only to a certain degree. Willson (2001:13), for example develops a model for a “transformed”<br />

planning process which is still clearly “influenced by societal values, public opinion, stakeholders and<br />

institutions, but [where] the process in turn may change societal values, public opinion, stakeholders and<br />

institutions.” In the end, instead of debating over “fixed” interests, it might indeed be preferable to say that<br />

interests are context-driven. If a group’s key interest/context is profit, its alliances are likely to vary, since<br />

money can be made both by exploiting and by protecting the environment. Other structural positions are<br />

less subject to opportunistic change, however.


141<br />

investments in Central Europe. 33<br />

Bankwatch's mission is “to prevent environmentally<br />

and socially harmful impacts of international development finance, and to promote<br />

alternative solutions and public participation” (see www.bankwatch.org). While pursuing<br />

typical environmentalist aims like “stopping environmentally and socially destructive<br />

policies and projects of International Financial Institutions in Central and Eastern Europe,<br />

and promot[ing] alternatives,” Bankwatch also stresses goals such as the following (ibid):<br />

To create public awareness about International Financial Institutions activities in<br />

Central and Eastern European countries and their social and environmental impacts.<br />

To promote public participation in the decision making process about policies and<br />

projects of International Financial Institutions, on the local, national and regional<br />

levels.<br />

To help non-governmental environmental organisations and citizen groups to monitor<br />

what the International Financial Institutions are doing in the Central and Eastern<br />

Europe.<br />

Transparency and democracy in decision-making thus represent concepts of the<br />

communicative rationality approach that resonate with practitioners far beyond the<br />

confines of communicative theorizing. In Europe, the UN ECE Aarhus Convention and<br />

the EU White Paper on European Governance remain the most important official policy<br />

documents recognizing the importance of access to information on the environment and<br />

public participation.<br />

4.4.2 Communicative Rationality as a Framework for EU Transport Policy<br />

As noted above, the literature on communicative rationality as a framework for<br />

transport policy is still somewhat inchoate. One explicit attempt to “contribute to the<br />

expanding literature on communicative and rhetorical practices by connecting these<br />

33<br />

See especially the “Billions for Sustainability?” Briefings on EU pre-accession funding which<br />

Bankwatch now puts out annually together with Friends of the Earth Europe (all three existing reports<br />

downloadable under http://www.bankwatch.org/publications/index.html).


142<br />

approaches to the field of transport planning” (p.669) is Tore Langmyhr’s (2000) article<br />

“The Rhetorical Side of Transport Planning”. Based on a case study of transport<br />

planning in the Norwegian medium size city of Trondheim, Langmyhr discusses different<br />

rhetorical arguments over the construction of a bypass road and over the introduction of a<br />

road pricing scheme. Although Langmyhr’s abstract promises an outline for “normative<br />

framework based on communicative planning theory”, the core of the case study in fact<br />

consists of an evaluation of planners’ (largely successful) use of opportunistic rhetoric in<br />

order to assure a political majority for the projects. At one point Langmyhr ambitiously<br />

reverts to Forester’s (1989) four “critical pragmatist,” Habermas-inspired, abstract<br />

concepts of “comprehensibility”, “sincerety”, “legitimacy”, and “truth” as guiding posts<br />

for “good communication,” only to immediately retract from the ideal of distortion-free<br />

information as “unreachable” (p. 680). In the end, Langmyhr ends up promoting rather<br />

than critiquing privileged transport decision-makers’ increasing use of rhetorical<br />

strategies since, as he argues, with “a larger transportation land-use system than before<br />

[and] an expanded set of societal values … planning authorities are in need of persuasion<br />

competence to justify their expertise” (p. 684, my emphasis). This might be true, yet a<br />

persuasive, retroactive justification of expert decisions is likely not what Habermas had<br />

in mind with regard to ideal speech situations.<br />

In a related piece, Langmyhr (2001) discusses the overall rationality of transport<br />

investment packages, arguing that such package policies involving several modes “entail<br />

some specific possibilities and traps in planning and decision-making processes” (p.157).<br />

In this article, Langmyhr again uses Norwegian national transport policy to compare “the<br />

instrumental rationality approach” focused on means-end rationality and efficiency with


143<br />

the “communicative rationality” approach which emphasizes interaction and process.<br />

This time, Langmyhr aims to demonstrate how a communicative rationality perspective<br />

ends up with a different set of pros and cons regarding the issue of investment packages<br />

than a traditional perspective emphasizing instrumental rationality. This aim is both<br />

interesting and relevant. In the article itself, however, Langmyhr then surprisingly<br />

categorizes the cunning practice of using investment packages to couple unpopular<br />

measures (e.g. road pricing and fees) with popular ones (e.g. local expansion of<br />

infrastructure with national funds) in the “pro-category” of the communicative rationality<br />

perspective – simply because “the potential for consensus building is enhanced” by this<br />

practice. So it seems to me that some proponents of the communicative approach have to<br />

distinguish more clearly between genuinely “communicative” settings where supposedly<br />

unbiased actors shape policy processes, and bastardizations of such ideal typical<br />

situations in which planners, public officials and/or bureaucratic decision-makers simply<br />

better sell (and thus ultimately achieve) largely preset agendas through opportunistic<br />

packaging of arguments and resources.<br />

In a wide-ranging assessment of communicative rationality as a possible<br />

alternative to conventional transport planning approaches, Richard Willson (2001)<br />

presents a sophisticated analysis of the current state of transport planning in developed<br />

countries, making several excellent points that cannot be recounted in detail here.<br />

Ultimately, his answer to whether communicative rationality represents a promising<br />

model for transportation planning is that “the promise is substantial” (p.25) but also that<br />

the promise alone “is insufficient to displace the traditional model” (p.23). At the outset<br />

of the article, Willson, like others before him, posits the communicative approach in


144<br />

square opposition to the orthodox approach of instrumental rationality, which is<br />

supported by an epistemology of scientific objectivism. Willson is aware that his critique<br />

of the technocratic, systems-analytical roots of planning, and of transport planning in<br />

particular, is neither new nor original. The real starting point of Willson’s argument is<br />

therefore not based on the obvious and now widely noted failures of instrumental<br />

rationality and the related scientific methodologies, but rather on the observation that the<br />

real-life expressions of the supposedly “scientific” transport planning rationalities are<br />

much more selective and strategic than true instrumental rationality would allow for. So<br />

ironically, following this line of argumentation, communicative rationality is in part<br />

about bringing the kind of “good” (i.e. unstrategic) rationalism back into the transport<br />

planning process that current practice has lost by not more strictly adhering to its<br />

scientific rationalist roots. In Willson’s (2001:6) words:<br />

Conventional transportation planning practice reflects a tension between the espoused<br />

theory [of instrumental rationality] just described and a theory-in-use of strategic<br />

rationality. By strategic rationality, I mean a form of rationality that is oriented toward<br />

achieving political action.<br />

Unfortunately, Willson ultimately leaves this tension unresolved. He has read<br />

Flyvbjerg and is therefore aware of the argument that “the context for rationality is power<br />

– power that turns rationality into rationalization.” (p.24). He nevertheless maintains that<br />

“communicative rationality is a desirable and practical approach to transportation<br />

planning” (p.25). As sketched out in the article, communicative rationality mainly<br />

amounts to a conflict-solving strategy which is already in part “employed by effective<br />

transportation planning practitioners” and which he admits has a potential limited<br />

applicability to “a ‘blank slate’ planning exercise undistorted by power and constrained


145<br />

by government regulation and funding formulae,” rendering it essentially useless for the<br />

complex context of EU policy making (quotes from pp.24-25). Nevertheless, his attempt<br />

to apply a communicative rationality form of transport planning to the specific transport<br />

policy of parking provision for rail transit station areas remains an interesting exercise<br />

that might be applied to the European context as well. Moreover, table 4.2, taken from<br />

his article, provides a useful summary comparison of traditional (“instrumental”) and<br />

communicative rationality approaches.<br />

Table 4.2 Comparing Instrumental and Communicative Rationality<br />

Issue Instrumental Rationality Communicative Rationality<br />

1. Role of the<br />

Planner<br />

2. Purpose of<br />

planning<br />

3. Planning<br />

Process<br />

Expert/analyst. Often a specialist<br />

(e.g. modeling, community affairs,<br />

finance, etc.). Official role is<br />

objective, but usually plays a<br />

political role<br />

Problem solving and optimization,<br />

with a rational decision-maker as<br />

the client. Finding the best solution<br />

for a fixed and known set of ends.<br />

A sequence of linear steps (with<br />

feedback). Assumes that facts and<br />

values can be addressed separately.<br />

Action follows knowledge.<br />

4.Communication Planners’ communication is<br />

assumed to provide accurate<br />

representation of facts and values;<br />

has standard meaning outside of<br />

action.<br />

5. Problem<br />

framing<br />

6. Analysis /<br />

Modeling<br />

Source: Willson (2001:14)<br />

Problems can be defined and<br />

bounded in a single frame; problems<br />

can be broken into pieces and<br />

recombined; problems can be<br />

defined in the absence of solutions:<br />

problems can be solved.<br />

Reductionism, reliance on data and<br />

models as forms of inquiry.<br />

Knowledge is empirically<br />

established.<br />

Communicative expert with technical<br />

knowledge and skill. Plays multiple<br />

roles – process design, activist<br />

mediation, education and technical<br />

roles. Self discloses roles.<br />

Reaching an understanding that<br />

facilitates action. Increasing capacity<br />

for reasoned deliberation and<br />

democratic decision-making.<br />

Recursive process: fact, value and<br />

discovery are interlinked. Emphasizes<br />

learning and consensus building. Is<br />

invented/modified as part of the<br />

planning activity. Action and<br />

knowledge are simultaneous.<br />

Communicative processes produce<br />

meaning and linguistic “action”.<br />

Planners seeks to improve the validity<br />

with which claims are made, e.g.<br />

truthfulness, legitimacy and sincerity.<br />

Multiple problem definitions and<br />

frames are acknowledged; problems are<br />

broadly bounded. Planning actively<br />

engages multiple problem frames, seeks<br />

creative redefinition.<br />

Quick-response models used along with<br />

other forms of knowing. Modeling<br />

claims are part of discourse.


146<br />

4.5 Political Economy<br />

Only through critical re-engagement with political-economy … can we hope to reestablish<br />

a conception of social justice as something to be fought for as a key value<br />

within an ethics of political solidarity built across different places.<br />

David Harvey (1996:360)<br />

4.5.1 Introducing the Framework<br />

In the discursive framework of political economy, the overarching theme or goal<br />

is not the “sustainable” growth of the economy or the preservation of the Earth’s<br />

ecological balance but simply and plainly “equity.” Equity is interpreted most commonly<br />

in terms of social (and, slightly more problematically, environmental) justice. The key<br />

unit of analysis is thus society. In the following sections, I also recognize several<br />

political economy approaches that are more concerned with spatial distributional aspects<br />

than with social ones, since the respective spaces are ultimately connected to different<br />

populations. The key relevance for policy lies in political economy’s focus on<br />

redistributive action.<br />

Like renunciation approaches (and, to a lesser extent,<br />

communicative rationality), political economy approaches are to be understood as<br />

alternatives, not complements, of the dominant approach of ecological modernization,<br />

and most political economy approaches are explicitly anti-capitalist.<br />

David Harvey’s (1996) much debated Justice, Nature and the Geography of<br />

Difference provides a useful example for an academic study written within the discursive<br />

framework of political economy. In the book, Harvey in fact provides an explicit critique<br />

of the ecological modernization framework (pp.382-3):<br />

As a discourse, ecological modernization internalizes conflict. …. It can be<br />

appropriated by multinational corporations to legitimize a global grab to manage all of<br />

the world’s resources. Indeed, it is not impossible to imagine a world in which big


147<br />

industry (certain segments), big governments (including the World Bank) and<br />

establishment, high tech big science can get to dominate the world even more than<br />

they currently do in the name of “sustainability,” ecological modernization and<br />

appropriate global management of the supposedly fragile health of planet earth.<br />

Against this threat, Harvey is sympathetic to the environmental justice movement<br />

– a key variant of political economy approaches – because it “advances a discourse<br />

radically at odds with the standard view and ecological modernization.<br />

Putting<br />

inequalities at the top of the environmental agenda directly challenges the dominant<br />

discourses” (p.385). Unlike green environmental groups like WWF, NRDC or<br />

Greenpeace, who fight for the protection of wild land and endangered species, the<br />

environmental justice movement, as Harvey points out, “puts the survival of people in<br />

general, and of the poor and marginalized in particular, at the center of its concerns”<br />

(p.386). Harvey is more skeptical, however, of the movement’s so-called “militant<br />

particularist” tendencies that overemphasize doctrines of local cultural autonomy and<br />

place-bound politics to the point where “not-in-my-backyard” politics simply mutate to<br />

generalized “not-in-anyone’s-backyard” principles. 34<br />

Yet as an urban theorist, Harvey is<br />

practically forced to theoretically engage with the environmental justice movement, since<br />

it is one of the few movements that explicitly refocus environmental problem perception<br />

away from emission, pollution and biodiversity issues towards issues that directly affect<br />

local communities, such as health impacts, noise or economic affordability. Political<br />

economy approaches more generally and the environmental justice movement in<br />

particular are thus representative of what is sometimes called the “brown agenda” of<br />

34 To provide a perfect, very self-aware European example of this: On their web-page, the European activist<br />

NGO ASEED advertises their “Map on Activities on Transport in Europe” (MATE) materials with the<br />

following words: “With the p. booklet, you will be able to find out about new transport plans in your part of<br />

the continent, and also who to contact in case you might not like a six lane motorway in your backyard (or<br />

anybody else’s backyard)” (http://www.aseed.net/publications/publications.htm#mate, assessed May 2002).


148<br />

environmental policy. Table 4.3 (below) provides an overview of the key differences<br />

between so-called “brown” versus “green” agenda environmental policy. Central issues<br />

such as the redistribution of both positive growth benefits and negative environmental<br />

impacts are not addressed to the same extent in any other discursive framework. 35<br />

Power<br />

struggles over environmental resources, especially at the local level, are key themes in<br />

the political economy framework.<br />

Given the strongly local activist roots of most larger environmental organizations<br />

fighting against further transport infrastructure expansion in Europe, it is not surprising<br />

that most of them employ a mix of both “green” and “brown” arguments (sometimes<br />

mixing them to a point where it obfuscates their overall argument). The same is true for<br />

the EU, whose Commission continually produces policy statements applicable to both,<br />

brown and green agendas, with an eco-modernist emphasis on the latter. Of late, the<br />

Environment Directorate’s urban policies have emphasized land use and brownfields<br />

issues, as well as more standard green environment themes (see Commission of the<br />

European Communities 1998a; Commission of the European Communities and Expert<br />

Group on the Urban Environment 2001g). Meanwhile, the EU’s general Urban Agenda<br />

(Commission of the European Communities 1997a) also emphasizes “brown” issues such<br />

as unemployment and social exclusion. More generally, the EU is of course also quite<br />

conscious of the need to consider distributive aspects of environmental problems.<br />

Typically, these aspects are (more or less implicitly) subsumed under mentions of “social<br />

sustainability” or “social cohesion.”<br />

35 Note that a process-oriented framework such as communicative rationality can in principle not be faulted<br />

for failing to pre-specify negative substantive outcomes such as inequality or environmental destruction.


149<br />

Table 4.3 “Brown” Agenda versus “Green” Agenda Environmental Policy<br />

“Brown Agenda”<br />

“Green Agenda”<br />

Problem perception<br />

regarding<br />

- First order impact Human health >> “Society”<br />

- Timing<br />

Immediate<br />

- Scale<br />

Local<br />

- Worst affected Lower-income groups<br />

- Economy Focus on problems related to<br />

poverty (affordability)<br />

Attitude towards<br />

- Nature<br />

- People<br />

- Environmental<br />

Services<br />

Aspects emphasized in<br />

relation to transport<br />

Manipulate to serve human<br />

needs<br />

Work with<br />

Provide more<br />

Local Pollution, Noise<br />

Traffic Accidents<br />

Access & affordability problems<br />

Ecosystem health,<br />

Biodiversity >> “Nature”<br />

Delayed<br />

Regional and global<br />

Future generations<br />

Focus on problems related to<br />

affluence<br />

(over-consumption)<br />

Protect and work with<br />

Educate<br />

Use Less /<br />

Use more efficiently<br />

Impact of infrastructures on<br />

natural habitats and species<br />

Global warming,<br />

Global emissions<br />

for disadvantaged groups<br />

Typical Proponent “Urbanist” “Environmentalist”<br />

Discursive Framework Political Economy Radical version: Renunciation<br />

Managerial (weaker) Version:<br />

Ecological Modernization<br />

Source: Adapted and expanded from McGranahan and Satterwaite (2000)<br />

4.5.2 Political Economy as a Framework for EU Transport Policy<br />

To researchers and theorists coming from a society-oriented political economy<br />

perspective, the differential access and mobility constraints of people depending on<br />

income, age, class, race or gender are crucial aspects of sustainability analyses. A few<br />

examples from the general transport literature serve to illustrate the approach. For one,<br />

many studies show that poor people are typically also transport-poor, i.e. either<br />

dependent on inadequate public transit or walking. Even for Los Angeles, the epitome of<br />

the 20 th century car-city, Meyerhoff, Micozzi and Rowen (1992:153) found that “for the<br />

very poor, accessibility to transportation is a major factor influencing the capacity to<br />

satisfy even the most rudimentary needs, such as food, shelter, employment, and medical


150<br />

care.” 36<br />

Schaeffer and Sclar’s (1980:111ff) classic account Access for All strove to<br />

illustrate how reliance on automobile transport has severely restricted the mobility of<br />

youth and the elderly. More recently, environmental justice-oriented scholars such as<br />

Bullard and Johnson (1997:1) have reminded us that “transportation development policies<br />

did not emerge in a race- and class-neutral society.” In the same volume, Holmes<br />

(1997:22) shows how “poor people and people of color … pay the highest social,<br />

economic and environmental costs and receive the fewest benefits from an automobiledominated<br />

transportation system.”<br />

In addition to this, a large number of studies have pointed to gender-imbalances in<br />

transport, showing how women have less access to cars, and are thus also more likely to<br />

be captive transit riders, i.e. passenger with no other modal choice. 37 Meanwhile,<br />

women’s domestic care-taking responsibilities typically require more localized, off-peak<br />

trip-making – a need very poorly met in most communities (for an overview of the<br />

gender and transport problematique see Grieco, Pickup et al. 1989; Hamilton, Jenkins et<br />

al. 1991; Levy 1992; Rosenbloom 1993; Turner and Fouracre 1995; Wachs 1998;<br />

Hamilton 2000; Peters 2000).<br />

In pointing out these differences, political economy-oriented scholars are mainly<br />

interested in the distributional effects of transport infrastructure investments. The typical<br />

research questions they ask point to the unequal benefits accruing to various social<br />

groups or, if more spatially-oriented, to different regions. A standard criticism by<br />

environmental NGOs is that international development institutions like the World Bank<br />

36 Eric Mann (1997) further illustrates how Los Angeles’ heavily subsidized new rail system is largely<br />

benefiting white suburban commuters, while the proposed fare hikes and service cuts for the much more<br />

extensive inner-city bus systems were to disproportionately affect poor minority households.<br />

37 Interestingly, according to Black (1995:302), the now widely used distinction between “choice” and<br />

“captive” riders was first made by Louis Keefer in a Pittsburgh Area Transportation study around 1960.


151<br />

or the European Investment Bank favor efficiency and growth over equity concerns, and<br />

this certainly also applies to the EU’s transport agenda. International lending criteria give<br />

priority to transport projects for so-called ‘strategic’ infrastructures for high-speed modes<br />

and longer-distance links at the expense of more local, lower-speed, accessibility<br />

enhancing interventions that are more relevant to the life situations to the poorest<br />

segments of the population (for some summary accounts, see Dimitriou 1992; Barter<br />

1998; Hook 1998b). This bias certainly also holds true for the European Union’s<br />

ambitious Trans-European Transport Network program. Kai Lemberg’s (1995) case<br />

study on the decision-making process concerning fixed transport links across the Baltic<br />

Sea in Scandinavia is a perfect example of a political economy approach to EU transport<br />

policy. Lemberg finds that<br />

when analysing benefits and costs of a transportation project or (alternative) networks<br />

we must always ask: to the benefit of whom? and at the cost of whom? Unfortunately<br />

these questions have not generally been put in the public reports on the three [Trans-]<br />

European links in Denmark.<br />

(p. 281)<br />

Interestingly, Lemberg’s case study shows that a political majority for (more<br />

environmentally sustainable) bored railway tunnels was converted into a majority for<br />

combined motorway/railway bridges mainly through the effective lobbying efforts of the<br />

European Roundtable of Industrialists. He documents how this organization of large<br />

European companies, with the support of the EC commission, the Danish motor lobby,<br />

and powerful trade union leaders was able to use its resources and connections to<br />

influence the decisions in the Danish national parliament in their favor, although “no<br />

proof has been given that the Great Belt Bridge and the Sound Bridge constitute the most<br />

economical use of resources in transport policy” (Lemberg 1995:284). In the opinion of


152<br />

equity-oriented political economists, Trans-European Networks are thus largely designed<br />

to support the interests of powerful, trans-national private sector interests. Since the socalled<br />

“missing links” are largely intended to eliminate “bottlenecks” (also see Chapter 6)<br />

and improve international through traffic, the benefits to the local economies in which the<br />

links are to be built are likely to be relatively minor. Nevertheless, political economists<br />

point out, the local and regional governments are still expected to shoulder a major part<br />

of the financial burden of constructing the infrastructures.<br />

Political economists increasingly use discourse analysis to point to persisting<br />

inequalities and discrepancies between rhetoric and reality in the transport sector. 38<br />

A<br />

concise presentation of a such a discourse-oriented political economy perspective in<br />

transport was recently published by Guy Baeten in his article Tragedy of the Highway:<br />

Empowerment, disempowerment and the politics of sustainability discourses and<br />

practices. Chapter 2 already quoted his political-economy definition of sustainable<br />

transport. His overall argument, summarized in the abstract, is the following:<br />

The orthodox sustainable transport vision leads to the further empowerment of<br />

technocratic and elitist groups in society while simultaneously contributing to the<br />

further disempowerment of those marginalized social groups who were already<br />

bearing the burden of the environmental problems resulting from a troubled transport<br />

system. … The issues of transport inequality and transport poverty should be reinserted<br />

into the dominant transport polity [sic] debates and practices.<br />

(Baeten 2000:69)<br />

There are several important aspects to this transport-oriented political economy<br />

argument, which is why I shall discuss the article in some detail here. For one, Baeten is<br />

one of the few European advocates for an environmental justice perspective to<br />

38 Clearly, I would include myself in this category.


153<br />

sustainable transport. Quoting Bullard (1990), 39 he criticizes the fact that “ the simple<br />

fact that environmental inequalities reinforce and are reinforced by social inequalities is<br />

hardly taken up by current debates on sustainable transport” (p.71). Quoting Sachs<br />

(1993), Baeten subsequently attacks “globalized environmentalism” as an undemocratic,<br />

technocratic endeavour “run by an international elite” that has little interest in addressing<br />

environmental problems at the local level. He also reinserts the issue of “class” into this<br />

debate, ultimately classifying (and rejecting) middle class environmentalism as “a<br />

conservative movement, in the sense that it does not challenge capitalism: […] it allows<br />

capitalism to adjust to its ecological contradictions.” Most importantly, he concludes that<br />

“such a stance, clearly, is highly compatible with [mainstream] sustainability rhetoric”<br />

(p.72). In the end, only the left is left to reveal the “’bourgeois character’ of<br />

contemporary environmentalism” (p.73). 40<br />

To Baeten, exclusion is a central problem in<br />

transport planning, and it is one that is ignored by mainstream sustainability discourses.<br />

To him, sustainable transport in its current rhetorical form is an unjust concept, since it<br />

privileges policy measures designed to further advance the mobility needs of the rich and<br />

powerful:<br />

39 Note that while Bullard’s 1990 book Dumping in Dixie is in fact not explicitly focusing on transport<br />

issues, Bullard subsequently edited (with Glenn S. Johnson) Just Transportation: Dismantling Race and<br />

Class Barriers to Mobility, which at least to my knowledge is the only full length book exclusively<br />

dedicated to the topic of environmental justice in the context of transportation, albeit written in a North<br />

American context.<br />

40 Baeten uses Gare (1995) to further differentiate his class argument. Drawing upon Bourdieu, Gare<br />

describes a breakdown of modernist class relations into a post-modern constellation in which previously<br />

powerful classes (i.e. the domestic bourgeoisie) are increasingly being subordinated to the influence of a<br />

‘new international bourgeoisie’ and its pertaining new ‘service sub-class’ adhering to “a modern version of<br />

social Darwinism.” The supposed “ideological spearhead” of the new international bourgeoisie is post-<br />

Keynesian neo-classical economics “characterized by supply side economics, dismantling social welfare<br />

provisions, the deregulation of markets, the reduction of trade barriers and the rapid expansion of<br />

econometrics and computer modeling” (Baeten p.77). The new service sub-class – thought by Baeten to<br />

include service providers in the widest sense, including academics and consultants – shares the<br />

international consumer tastes and interests of the new bourgeoisie, despite the fact that this class has failed<br />

to gain any significant political power in the new system.


154<br />

Neither economists nor spatial planners have seriously addressed the matter of sociospatial<br />

polarization between the mobile wealthy and the immobile poor. On the<br />

contrary, current transport policy discourses and practices widen the gap between the<br />

mobile wealthy and the immobile poor, because they fail to take into account the<br />

socio-economic consequences of proposed policy measures.<br />

Unfortunately, Baeten’s description of the plight of the “immobile poor” remains<br />

vague and it is not clear how exactly their policy requirements differ from those of the<br />

“mobile wealthy.” He apparently interprets Swyngedouw’s (1993:322) statement that<br />

those “trapped in place, stripped of their capacity to move across space, will suffer in an<br />

age in which mobility has become an even more profitable and extremely powerful<br />

commodity” to mean that poor people are always less mobile than wealthy ones.<br />

In my view, this is a grossly oversimplified view. The “political economy of<br />

mobility” is infinitely more complicated. Socio-spatial polarization certainly exists. Yet<br />

a simple dualistic differentiation between “mobile wealthy” and “immobile poor” renders<br />

a disservice to the overall cause of political economy, because it does not represent the<br />

experience of many disempowered people. So we need to expand on Baeten a bit here.<br />

Firstly, a distinction needs to be made between the distances various social groups<br />

travel, and their means of travel. Secondly, the two are intricately linked. Housing and<br />

transportation are two key capital expenses for any household, and individual locational<br />

decisions and mode choices involve complicated trade-offs that vary greatly according to<br />

local contexts. A few general examples from around the world should suffice to make<br />

the point. In most developing country cities, the poor live in sprawling, often informal<br />

settlements far from the city center, and they spend up to six hours every day getting to<br />

and from home to work, thus traveling much greater distances than their middle class<br />

counterparts (cf. Gannon and Liu 1997). So here it is the poor who continually have to be


155<br />

“on the move” while the wealthy can afford to be more immobile. 41<br />

Mobility in the sense<br />

of daily commuting habits is a burden rather than a luxury. In these cities, only the<br />

middle class and the rich own cars, but normally there is a wide variety of both formal<br />

and informal public transport providing relatively high mobility to all but the very poor.<br />

Meanwhile, in extremely congested cities such as Sao Paulo or Bangkok, around-theclock<br />

gridlock affects everyone. 42<br />

In the end, the problem is less one of mobility within<br />

the city than of access to certain spaces, in particular gated communities and walled in<br />

office complexes. In socialist cities, by contrast, mobility patterns were centrally planned<br />

and neither housing nor employment were allocated according to market principles. And<br />

with the exemption of a very small elite, everyone took public transport and mobility<br />

patterns were less related to income. (This is now quickly changing, of course.) In<br />

Western industrialized cities, which are the focus of Baeten’s article, (auto)mobility is<br />

also less and less a matter of affordability, and congestion makes reduced mobility a<br />

desirable option. Given the attractiveness of many central city neighborhoods, many<br />

higher-income young urban professionals make a conscious choice to live close to their<br />

place of employment, sometimes even selling their cars. Finally, in the US, unmistakably<br />

the most automobilized country in the world, the mobility situation of the rich and the<br />

poor is quite contrary to the one in less developed countries, and housing-transportation<br />

trade-off work in almost opposite directions. Like everywhere else, higher-income<br />

households can make more flexible housing decisions, choosing, for example, a large<br />

single-family home close to a suburban rail-line or a gated penthouse apartment next to<br />

41 Note that “work” in most cases does not mean formal employment here. Yet even informal economy<br />

activities tend to be concentrate in the city center.<br />

42 Baeten is certainly right, however, as far as the exceptional mobility of the super-rich is concerned: in<br />

Sao Paulo in particular, high-level executives escape urban gridlock and violence by door-to-door<br />

commuting via helicopter. See Faiola (2002)


156<br />

(safe and clean) public transport. Poor minority households have rather limited housing<br />

choices, however. The cheapest housing is typically located in inner-city neighborhoods.<br />

Many job opportunities for low-skilled workers, by contrast, are in locations which are<br />

not adequately served by public transport. The poor thus incur a “spatial mismatch”<br />

between their low-income inner city residence and their best opportunities for<br />

employment, namely low-paid service sector jobs in suburban office parks, edge cities<br />

and malls that are only accessible by car. 43<br />

The upshot is that even the poor in the US<br />

tend to be individually mobile car owners.<br />

Baeten’s account also ignores gender differences in mobility. In the end, Baeten,<br />

whose key point is that “sustainable transport rhetoric does not address the deeply<br />

conflicting character of transport planning,” is himself partially guilty of not more clearly<br />

spelling out conflicts between environmental and social issues in transport. It seems<br />

dishonest to end with environmental justice/racism arguments that show that the poor are<br />

more affected by pollution. For obviously reasons, the poor also often lead less<br />

environmentally conscious lives in the sense that environmentalism is a luxury they<br />

cannot afford. Poor people drive older, more polluting cars, and they buy fewer ecofriendly<br />

products. 44<br />

Higher levels of environmental awareness typically correlate with<br />

43 The “spatial mismatch” hypothesis is of course still a hotly debated topic in American academia and<br />

beyond. For a historical perspective on the debate, see Kain (1968) and then Kain (1994). For some recent<br />

contributions, see Ilanfeldt and Sjoquist (1998), Taylor and Ong (1995), and McLafferty and Preston<br />

(1996) as well as Wyly (1996) and McLafferty and Preston (1992) for a gender perspective on spatial<br />

mismatch.<br />

44 This does not necessarily mean that poor people necessarily have a more negative overall impact on the<br />

environment than middle class people, however. Given that higher-income households typically also have<br />

higher levels of consumption, they still end up “polluting” more than lower-income households. Compare,<br />

for example, the yearly CO 2 emissions of a poor family of four that owns a smoke-belching old Ford but<br />

can barely afford to go on a few weekend trips with it with those of an environmentally conscious DINK<br />

couple that owns a modern low-emission car, goes on eco-tourist trips to Costa Rica and Nepal and<br />

occasionally flies off to London or Paris for weekend shopping trips. Frequent international long-distance<br />

travel indeed remains a privilege of the better-off.


157<br />

higher levels of education and income.<br />

This is an ongoing challenge for<br />

environmentalists and social activists both in Europe and elsewhere.<br />

Other political economy arguments are more framed in terms of a European coreperiphery<br />

divide, building on the implications of the different spatial metaphors related to<br />

European space. 45<br />

A common interpretation of the famous Blue Banana, for example,<br />

was that agglomerations outside the banana were “doomed to failure” in the competitive<br />

European hierarchy. While this is of course an overstatement, there is now strong<br />

empirical evidence confirming that European integration has been of much greater<br />

benefit to central regions than to peripheral regions in the South and the North (Cheshire<br />

1990). Goldsmith (1993:686) further reports that “falling transport costs have a<br />

significant effect on who performs well or badly.” So whatever the precise outline of the<br />

central European geopolitical powerhouse, there has long been a consensus that EU’s<br />

more peripheral regions are likely to be the losers. Spatially-oriented political economy<br />

concerns have also received much additional support through empirical evidence<br />

presented in the new national and regional development studies questioning road<br />

building’s positive effect on growth (also see the discussion under 2.5.4). In the end,<br />

these researchers then argue, the TENs are likely to increase regional disparity in Europe,<br />

rather than foster overall integration and cohesion (as modernizationists like to believe).<br />

Turning attention from academic scholars to local activists, one finds in the<br />

radical anti-capitalist group ASEED a most radical defender of social justice values.<br />

ASEED, a group of young leftist activists who have mounted an extensive network of<br />

45 Such spatial political economy approaches typically strongly rely on the concept of cohesion. Cohesion<br />

is one of the key “storylines” of EU decision-making, and it is analyzed in much more detail in chapter 5.


158<br />

resistance against the Trans-European Networks, gave itself the following mission<br />

statement (see http://www.aseed.net/about.htm), worth quoting in full:<br />

Action for Solidarity, Equality, Environment and Diversity (A SEED) Europe is<br />

against the exploitation of both people and nature. We believe the fundamental causes<br />

of ecological destruction and maldevelopment are patterns of domination and control.<br />

These stem from patriarchy, colonialism, scientific reduction, imperialism and the<br />

more recent imposition of a ruthless, "free" market globalisation. This globalisation<br />

process is being driven by the increasing mobility of capital. Transnational<br />

corporations and their institutional aides such as the World Trade Organisation and<br />

international financial institutions concentrate global wealth and power by breaking<br />

into and destroying local markets and taking away local decision making. Economic<br />

globalisation intensifies inequity on all levels, concentrates resources in the hands of a<br />

shrinking proportion of the world's population. Competition for profits becomes the<br />

main determinant of society. Globalisation leads to every region and individual<br />

competing against each other, creating a vicious downwards spiral where the worst<br />

social and environmental conditions become dominant. Our current economic system<br />

regards nature as a resource to be exploited, which stands in sharp contrast to the<br />

symbiotic relationship of humans as a part of nature. A SEED Europe strives towards<br />

cultural and biological diversity. We reject and work to end discrimination on the basis<br />

of age, class, disability, ethnicity, gender, race, religious belief and sexual preferences.<br />

We support the right of individuals and communities to determine their own lives.<br />

Vital tools towards these aims are: promoting grass root organisation, education,<br />

mobilisation and non-violent direct action such that people are able to act for social<br />

and environmental justice from local to global level. (Lyon, October 1996)<br />

Most political economy approaches are much more moderate, of course. For<br />

example, the goal statement of the European Federation for Transport and Environment<br />

(T&E), the umbrella organization of (alternative) traffic clubs in Europe, also centers its<br />

mission around societal factors of transport, but the organization is much more willing to<br />

work within current societal and political structures, even stressing “efficiency” aspects<br />

(see http://www.t-e.nu):<br />

Transport affects everyone; it must function efficiently while causing minimum<br />

damage to the environment and human health. However, this damage seems to be<br />

increasing rather than diminishing. For this reason T&E speaks out for sustainable<br />

transport in Europe.


159<br />

In sum, political economy arguments are both varied and wide-ranging, but<br />

always united in their ultimate focus on the quadruple question “Who benefits, who<br />

suffers, why and how?”.<br />

4.6 Renunciation<br />

4.6.1 Introducing the Framework<br />

In many ways, the renunciation discursive framework is the classical<br />

environmentalist discourse, criticizing the over-consumption and depletion of natural<br />

resources and urging a return to a less resource-intensive way of living. The overarching<br />

theme is ecological balance, and the key unit of analysis is nature. Renunciation<br />

approaches, the most radical of which are also anti-modern, are based on the fundamental<br />

insight that it is impossible for all economies in the world to keep growing and thus<br />

produce environmental impacts in the same way that Western industrial nations have in<br />

the past century. Supporters of the Renunciation discourse do not share ecological<br />

modernization scholars’ (or practitioners) faith in technology’s ability to ensure that<br />

future growth is clean and ecological. The policy dimension for the framework is<br />

protective, eco-centric action.<br />

The most important, and also most stereotypical example of a globally relevant<br />

renunciation discourse is the Deep Ecology / Ecosophy approach. Deep Ecology has a<br />

strong moralistic, and even fundamentalist overtone. Deep Ecology principles are broad<br />

and not easily translatable into one concrete political program. However, in 1984, Deep<br />

Ecology leaders Arne Naess and George Sessions developed an eight-point platform for<br />

supporters of the movement that has become a frequently-cited reference for Deep


160<br />

Ecology’s core values and beliefs. Table 4.4 presents this Eight-Point Platform of Deep<br />

Ecology.<br />

A key difference between Deep Ecology and many other environmental<br />

approaches is that Deep Ecology’s starting point is not the value of nature to humans, but<br />

rather the intrinsic, essential value of nature and all beings. Also, Deep Ecology is<br />

committed to action, but not so much at the political as at the individual, personal level.<br />

This includes a “deep questioning” of personal lifestyles and experiences, “self<br />

realization” and the need for each individual to think out his or her “ecosophy”. The<br />

founding father of Deep Ecology, 46 the Norwegian philosopher Arne Naess, is rather up-<br />

front about the normative, fundamentalist nature of such an approach (quoted in<br />

Drengson and Inoue 1995:8):<br />

By an ecosophy I mean a philosophy of ecological harmony or equilibrium. A<br />

philosophy as a kind of sofia (or) wisdom, is openly normative, it contains both norms,<br />

rules, postulates, value priority announcements and hypotheses concerning the state of<br />

affairs in our universe. Wisdom is policy wisdom, prescription, not only scientific<br />

description and prediction. The details of an ecosophy will show many variations due<br />

to significant differences concerning not only the ‘facts’ of pollution, resources,<br />

population, etc. but also value priorities. 47<br />

46 Note that in his 1972 talk that coined the movement’s name, Naess quite explicitly differentiated between<br />

a “long-range deep ecology movement” which deeply questioned fundamental values and a “shallow<br />

ecology movement” which, translated into today’s context and terminology, is essentially the ecological<br />

modernization approach. (A 1973 article based on Naess’ foundational talk is reprinted in Drengson and<br />

Inonue 1995.)<br />

47 Naess emphasizes that supporters of the eight platform principles can hold a wide range of “ultimate”<br />

viewpoints that make up their own, individual ecosophy. Naess’ calls his own ultimate philosophy<br />

“Ecosophy T”, and it is on this basis that Naess supports the Deep Ecology platform. Drengson (1999)<br />

characterizes Naess’ “Ecosophy T” as a philosophy incorporating elements from the Norwegian outdoorliving<br />

movement friluftsliv, from Gandian non-violence, from Mahayana Buddhism and from Spinozan<br />

pantheism.


161<br />

Table 4.4 The Eight Points of Deep Ecology<br />

1. The well-being and flourishing of human and non-human life on Earth have value in<br />

themselves (synonyms: intrinsic value, inherent worth). These values are independent<br />

of the usefulness of the non-human world for human purposes.<br />

2. Richness and diversity of life forms contribute to the realization of these values and<br />

are also values in themselves.<br />

3. Humans have no right to reduce this richness and diversity except to satisfy vital<br />

needs.<br />

4. The flourishing of human life and cultures is compatible with a substantially smaller<br />

human population. The flourishing of non-human life requires a smaller human<br />

population. 48<br />

5. Present human interference with the non-human world is excessive, and the situation<br />

is rapidly worsening.<br />

6. Policies must therefore be changed. These policies affect basic economic,<br />

technological, and ideological structures. The resulting state of affairs will be deeply<br />

different from the present.<br />

7. The ideological change will be mainly that of appreciating life quality (dwelling in<br />

situations of inherent value) rather than adhering to an increasingly higher standard of<br />

living. There will be a profound awareness of the difference between bigness and<br />

greatness.<br />

8. Those who subscribe to the foregoing points have an obligation directly or indirectly<br />

to try to implement the necessary changes.<br />

Sources:<br />

multiple, e.g. Devall and Sessions (1985:70-73), Sessions (1995), Drengson (1999)<br />

Deep Ecology is critical of mainstream “industrial culture” that creates<br />

monocultures in agriculture and forestry, destroys indigenous cultures and habitats and<br />

inflates desires to inspire consumption beyond what is vitally necessary. In their place,<br />

the movement’s ecocentric supporters often praise the place-specific, vernacular<br />

technology practices of aboriginal and indigenous people. Deep Ecology also sees itself<br />

compatible with Christian eco-theologies “based on a reverential spirit for Creation”<br />

(Drengson 1999), with Buddhist thought, Ghandian philosophies of non-violence, and<br />

with activist movements such as Bioregionalism. Deep Ecology is also broadly<br />

48 The Deep Ecology literature I have read is remarkably silent in its discussion of this problematic Neo-<br />

Malthusian principle which implicitly bases the foundation of a more ecological society on population<br />

reduction.


162<br />

compatible with the Gaia hypothesis, which also presents an all-encompassing outlook on<br />

life as one interconnected whole. 49<br />

The Institute for Deep Ecology is a useful example of an organization that has<br />

attempted to translate such an ecocentric, low-impact approach to human life into<br />

guidelines for daily decision-making (see www.deep-ecology.org/ide_values.html):<br />

We humbly acknowledge our place in the web of life that sustains us. … We commit<br />

ourselves to living more lightly and less violently on Earth in the energy and natural<br />

resources we consume. … Our intention is to reduce, re-use, recycle,…. participate in<br />

or contribute to an ecological restoration activity, … seek affiliations and collaborative<br />

projects as a means to reduce consumption and increase effectiveness, select locations<br />

and plan for programs in ways that minimize travel, especially the solo use of<br />

automobiles, and increase the use of sustainable, local products. [emphasis added]<br />

Traditional conservationist movements aimed at wilderness and wildlife<br />

protection are of course also complementary to the Deep Ecology project. The basic<br />

“protect nature for nature’s sake” argument is an implied, albeit now largely unstated<br />

feature of most current environmental activism.<br />

Most large environmental organizations active in the European Union and in the<br />

accession countries are much less radical in their formulations than the Deep Ecology<br />

platform. The following goal statements of some of the most influential NGOs active in<br />

Europe illustrate how conservation and biodiversity issues are now typically framed<br />

within a larger agenda of environmental and civic activism. Euronatur and BirdLife<br />

49 The Gaia Hypothesis, championed by the British chemist James Lovelock, views the planet as a giant<br />

self-regulating organism (Lovelock 1979; Lovelock 1988). For Lovelock (1988:206, 212) “Gaia is a<br />

religious as well as a scientific concept” meaning that “God and Gaia, theology and science, even physics<br />

and biology are not separate but a single way of thought.” The fact that it has been widely adopted as a<br />

New Age tenet certainly has not helped the credibility of Lovelock’s hypothesis. Nevertheless, the general<br />

concept of biotic regulation of the Earth has recently found some respectability among the biogeochemical<br />

community (Kaiser 2000).


163<br />

International, for example, demonstrate how once classic conservationist movements now<br />

have significantly broadened their horizons:<br />

We can only conserve nature with people and not against them - this is one of the<br />

fundamental ideas of the European Natural Heritage Fund (EURONA<strong>TU</strong>R). Our<br />

activities focus on the natural heritage in its diversity, which we endeavour to preserve<br />

for ourselves and for future generations. … The preservation of traditional cultural<br />

landscapes is one of EURONA<strong>TU</strong>R's fundamental aims. Moreover, we want to initiate<br />

a broad international dialogue to increase the quality of environment and life. 50<br />

Many of the pressures that threaten birds, their habitats and biodiversity also have<br />

adverse effects on local communities. Unsustainable use of natural resources deepens<br />

poverty as essential resources are exhausted. … Conservation that excludes people can<br />

lead to increased poverty, resentment and lack of co-operation. An alternative is to<br />

link biodiversity conservation with measures to meet people's needs, through<br />

sustainable economic development, poverty alleviation and improvement of local<br />

livelihoods with bottom-up decision-making. Through the integration of conservation<br />

and development, BirdLife International helps people to achieve a secure livelihood<br />

that is sustainable. This allows the values of natural ecosystems to be realised without<br />

damaging the resources on which human well-being depends. 51<br />

Greenpeace and Friends of the Earth International exemplify the classical allround<br />

perspective of activist environmental NGOs:<br />

Greenpeace is an independently funded organization that works to protect the<br />

environment. We challenge government and industry to halt harmful practices by<br />

negotiating solutions, conducting scientific research, introducing clean alternatives,<br />

carrying out peaceful acts of civil disobedience and educating and engaging the public.<br />

Greenpeace seeks to protect biodiversity in all its forms; prevent pollution of the<br />

earth’s oceans, land, air and fresh water; end all nuclear threats; promote peace, global<br />

disarmament and non-violence. 52<br />

Friends of the Earth International is a worldwide federation of national<br />

environmental organizations. This federation aims to protect the earth against further<br />

deterioration and repair damage inflicted upon the environment by human activities<br />

and negligence; preserve the earth's ecological, cultural and ethnic diversity; increase<br />

50<br />

See www.euronatur.org/euro_engl/start_E.htm. Note that EURONA<strong>TU</strong>R’s website might feature<br />

conservationist principles but that its policies are certainly at odds with Deep Ecology approaches. Also,<br />

given that key EURONA<strong>TU</strong>R sponsors include Lufthansa and DaimlerCrysler, this NGO is far from being<br />

anti-capitalist.<br />

51 See http://www.birdlife.net/people/index.cfm<br />

52 There is no specialized Greenpeace mission statement for Europe. The current quote is taken from the<br />

Greenpeace Canada website (www.greenpeace.ca)


164<br />

public participation and democratic decision-making. Greater democracy is both an<br />

end in itself and is vital to the protection of the environment and the sound<br />

management of natural resources; achieve social, economic and political justice and<br />

equal access to resources and opportunities for men and women on the local, national,<br />

regional and international levels; promote environmentally sustainable development<br />

on the local, national, regional and global levels. 53<br />

The German Branch of Friends of the Earth International, the Bund für Umwelt<br />

und Naturschutz Deutschland (Alliance for Environment and Nature Protection Germany,<br />

BUND) is a perfect example of how nature conservation “went mainstream” during the<br />

1980s and 90s. The BUND itself summarizes its own evolution from a conservationist<br />

movement to a broad activist organization as follows (see www.bund.net):<br />

BUND was founded in 1975 as a federation of pre-existing regional groups. Some<br />

local branches date back to 1913. BUND has its origins in the nature conservation<br />

movement. Today the organisation is one of the most powerful environmental<br />

organisations in Germany. BUND has 375,000 members and supporters. Members are<br />

active in some 2,200 local and regional groups, which do everything from lobbying<br />

work to practical nature conservation. BUND works on all of today's major<br />

environmental issues and is a well recognized lobbyist with a high media profile.<br />

Campaigning priorities are sustainable transport, fighting nuclear power, improving<br />

nature protection laws, and greening the German tax system. Internationally, BUND<br />

works on climate policy and is coordinating Friends of the Earth International´s<br />

campaign on the Rio+10 summit in 2002.<br />

Several large environmental organizations now specifically target the European<br />

Union and its policy-making. None of these take a clearly identifiable eco-centric<br />

renunciation perspective any more. For example, the European Environmental<br />

Bureau’s (EEB) specific mission is “to promote environmental policies and sustainable<br />

policies on the European Union level” (www.eeb.org). For the EEB,<br />

Sustainability is not purely a matter of environmental policies. Social, economic and<br />

cultural dimensions are relevant; the EU has a major influence beyond its own<br />

territory. The environmental dimensions of enlargement, the direct relationships with<br />

53 See http://www.foei.org/about/mission_statement.html.


165<br />

regions in the world and the general role of the EU in the global marketplace are areas<br />

of concern for the EEB;<br />

The European office of Friends of the Earth is also typical for the special lobbying<br />

offices NGOs have opened to monitor EU environment activities. 54<br />

FoEE is the largest environmental network in Europe working at grassroots level,<br />

consisting of 31 independent national groups in 30 countries with over 3000 local<br />

chapters. FoEE coordinates and supports the campaigns and projects of its member<br />

groups, which deal with a large variety of subjects such as traffic, waste, EUenlargement,<br />

EU structural funds, trade, tourism, climate change and biotechnology.<br />

Through these activities, FoEE aims to raise public awareness, enhance the<br />

participation of people and environmental citizens' organisations in political processes,<br />

and influence political decision-makers, especially at the European level.<br />

The European Policy office of the World Wildlife Fund (WWF) has even<br />

launched a special Accession Initiative seeking to “raising awareness of the threats and<br />

opportunities for nature conservation and sustainable development connected with the<br />

historic enlargement of the European Union.” 55<br />

Given these broadened agendas, we can conclude that the explicit eco-centrism of<br />

the discursive framework of renunciation really has no direct policy outlet in the<br />

European institutional landscape. Nature protection and conservation have mostly<br />

become mainstreamed into human-centric environmental discourses. 56<br />

What remains<br />

strong among environmentalists, however, is the view that human resource consumption<br />

has to be limited.<br />

54 Also, Climate Network Europe (CAN), the European Federation for Transport and Environment, the<br />

International Friends of Nature, WWF’s European office, the EEB, BirdLife International, Friends of the<br />

Earth and Greenpeace have formed the so-called “Green G8”, an alliance formed by eight of the largest<br />

European environmental organizations that have as many as 20 million individual members through various<br />

national organizations in Europe. They coordinate joint responses and recommendations to EU decision<br />

makers. For an overview brochure on their joint activities, see http://www.te.nu/Temp%20info/GreenG8Brochure.pdf.<br />

55 See http://www.panda.org/resources/programmes/epo/accession/<br />

56 This fits well with the historical explanation of the concept of ecological modernization Hajer presents.


166<br />

4.6.2 Renunciation as a Framework for EU Transport Policy<br />

”El socialismo puede llegar sólo en bicicleta.”<br />

José Antonio Viera-Gallo<br />

Assistant Secretary of Justice in the government of Salvador Allende<br />

With regard to transport aspects of the renunciation frameworks, the bicycle is<br />

both the symbolic and real-life champion of this approach. Non-motorized transport<br />

means zero-emission transport. More importantly, the production of bicycles is much<br />

less resource intensive than the production of cars and other high-tech self-propelled<br />

vehicles. One group within the ecology movement that has particularly focused on the<br />

role of transportation and on the automobile in the industrial society is Ivan Illich and his<br />

circle of friends. Widely regarded as one of the founding thinkers of the ecology<br />

movement, Illich’s approach differs from purely eco-centric approaches in its explicit<br />

focus on social and equity aspects of industrialization. Illich was convinced that “high<br />

quanta of energy degrade social relations just as inevitably as they destroy the physical<br />

milieu”. 57 He was also a fierce advocate of cycling, arguing that the bicycle is in fact a<br />

much more efficient means of transportation than any other mode. His basic argument,<br />

made in the mid-seventies and reiterated by countless sustainable transport advocates<br />

since, is simple:<br />

The model American male devotes more than 1,600 hours a year to his car …. to get<br />

7,500 miles: less than five miles per hour. In countries deprived of a transportation<br />

industry, people manage to do the same, walking wherever they want to go, and they<br />

allocate only 3 to 8 per cent of their society's time budget to traffic instead of 28 per<br />

cent.<br />

57 This quote is from a series of text extracts from “Energy and Equity” available in the Ivan Illich Archives<br />

of the University of Edinburgh’s Cognitive Science department under<br />

http://www.cogsci.ed.ac.uk/~ira/illich/.


167<br />

Man on a bicycle can go three or four times faster than the pedestrian, but uses five<br />

times less energy in the process. … Equipped with this tool, man outstrips the<br />

efficiency of not only all machines but all other animals as well. Bicycles are not only<br />

thermodynamically efficient, they are also cheap. With his much lower salary, the<br />

Chinese acquires his durable bicycle in a fraction of the working hours an American<br />

devotes to the purchase of his obsolescent car. … Eighteen bikes can be parked in the<br />

place of one car, thirty of them can move along in the space devoured by a single<br />

automobile. 58<br />

More importantly, however, Illich’s argument was also an anti-motorization plea<br />

which asked people to renounce the temptation of increasingly accelerated lifestyles both<br />

for environmental and social reasons (“Traffic nibbles away at lifetime”):<br />

Every increase in motorized speed creates new demands on space and time. The use of<br />

the bicycle is self-limiting. It allows people to create a new relationship between their<br />

life-space and their life-time, between their territory and the pulse of their being,<br />

without destroying their inherited balance. The advantages of modern self-powered<br />

traffic are obvious, and ignored. That better traffic runs faster is asserted, but never<br />

proved. Before they ask people to pay for it, those who propose acceleration should try<br />

to display the evidence for their claim. 59<br />

Illich was one of the first thinkers to focus on “the contradiction implicit in the<br />

joint pursuit of equity and industrial growth.” Since then, many of Illich’s colleagues and<br />

friends have produced ecological treatises important in their own right. Wolfgang Sachs,<br />

for example, has published numerous books and papers on the ecological and social<br />

failures of our current transport systems. More generally, he has also propagated the<br />

“virtue of enoughness” against the dominant approach of efficient resource management<br />

(Sachs 1999b). Sachs’ perspective is particularly interesting because it updates Illich’s<br />

fundamental argument about the need to decelerate traffic in a way that it results in a<br />

powerful mix of ecological modernization, reflexive modernization and renunciation<br />

“rationalities.” With Sachs, the renunciation of high-speed transport options appears as a<br />

58 Excerpted from the Chapters “The Industrialization of Traffic” and “Degrees of Self-Powered Mobility”<br />

in “Energy and Equity,” see http://www.cogsci.ed.ac.uk/~ira/illich/.<br />

59 Ibid.


168<br />

superior, intelligent solution which individuals are increasingly willing to consider<br />

precisely because in developed country contexts, high-speed mobility now has become<br />

the norm rather than the exception, and because fast-moving daily activity patterns have<br />

become too hectic and exhausting to be enjoyable. The car has become the victim of its<br />

own success, Sachs argues. As Sachs (1999a) summarizes: 60<br />

‘Faster’ and ‘Further’ – alongside the principle of ‘More’ – can be considered as the<br />

main leitmotifs of fossil-powered progress. … But in the setting of today's restlessly<br />

high-speed society, such a Utopia easily becomes exhausted and stale. … Where<br />

unceasing mobility turns into a stressful burden, a desire for leisureliness and<br />

unharriedness is likely to grow. Quite apart from environmental problems, pleasure in<br />

mobility is today increasingly intermingled with frustration. … With mass<br />

motorization the situation has changed, and the relative advantages the car once<br />

conferred have dwindled: the more cars, the less joy. Moreover, as soon as speed is a<br />

general expectation, gaining time is no longer a pleasure, but becomes an obligation.<br />

The power over space and time granted by transportation is becoming a duty rather<br />

than a privilege.… This shift in the emotional base of motorization is an important<br />

ingredient in the search for environ-mentally sound ways of transport. …<br />

Contemplating limits to further growth is a rational strategy against systemic overdevelopment,<br />

because restraint slows down the dynamics of expansion, avoids<br />

additional financial and social burdens, and opens space for planning alternatives. Not<br />

opting for further acceleration and interconnection will offer a range of opportunities<br />

for creating a socially appropriate transport system for the twenty-first century.<br />

Note that Sachs’ “virtue of enoughness” perspective is not strictly eco-centric or<br />

anti-modern but rather anti-utilitarian and non-economic in the sense that it is deeply<br />

conscious of alternative cultural meanings of “production” and “consumption”. Sharply<br />

criticizing “the World Resources Institute and other eco-development agencies” Sachs<br />

(1999b:14) argues that<br />

The interpretation of the state of the world in terms of “resources,” “management” and<br />

“efficiency” may appeal to planners and economists. But it continues to promote<br />

development as a cultural mission…. The more their language is adopted round the<br />

globe, the more difficult it will be to view nature with respect rather than simply as a<br />

resource to be exploited. [emphasis added]<br />

60 The following quotes are a much abbreviated version of the section “Lower Speeds and the Plurality of<br />

Timescales” in Chapter 12 of Planet Dialectics.


169<br />

Policy arguments in favor for less long-distance travel have also been made in the<br />

direct context of EU transport policy. For example, in their short article “Transport<br />

Policy in the EU: A Strategy for Sustainable Development,” Sarah Wixey and Steve Lake<br />

(1998) also stress the reduction of travel as the central aspect of any sustainable transport<br />

policy. Moreover, Wixey’s and Lake’s article is useful in spelling out antianthropocentric<br />

arguments for EU transport policy. In their definitional section (p. 2),<br />

Wixey and Lake argue that<br />

In practice, much of what passes for policy on ‘sustainable development’ has a much<br />

narrower remit. The chief focus of much policy claiming to be ‘sustainable’ is on<br />

issues more usefully placed under the category of ‘quality of life.’ [However,]<br />

sustainable development goes beyond a shallow environmental approach or short term<br />

concern for living standards. This paper is implicitly concerned with sustainability<br />

which may in general underpin debates over quality of life, but which addresses a<br />

global concern with limited resources and capacities. The differences are in matters of<br />

scope, in that sustainable development deals with a broader range of issues not all<br />

necessarily linked to questions of human welfare.<br />

In their subsequent discussion of EU transport policy, they come to the same<br />

conclusion I come to in this study, namely that “sustainable transport policy is largely<br />

subordinated to issues of ‘economic growth’ [and that] this seems to be the current<br />

approach taken to the issue of transport in the European Union” (p.3). In particular, they<br />

argue that<br />

Commitments to sustainable development declared in the Maastricht Treaty and the<br />

Fifth Environmental Action Programme (5EAP) cannot be maintained with the EU’s<br />

current TEN policy programme. The EU’s priority projects favour long distance<br />

mobility, gained at the expense of shorter distance transport. [By contrast] even a<br />

fairly basic appreciation of the notion of sustainable development would surely<br />

involve a commitment to reduction of the need to travel.


170<br />

Note that while I tend to agree with many of Wixley’s and Lake’s criticisms<br />

launched against EU transport policy, their article unfortunately leaves most of their<br />

assertions empirically unsubstantiated. This is also true for the above-implied direct<br />

trade off between long-distance and short-distance transport. 61<br />

As we have seen in many<br />

of the other sections of this chapter, scholars and practitioners working within other<br />

discursive frameworks would simply disagree with Wixley’s and Lake’s assertion that<br />

sustainable development necessarily includes a reduction in the need to travel. Even very<br />

environmentally-minded political economists are still more likely to argue for a<br />

sustainability definition that would include increased access and mobility of the poor<br />

(which are then preferably to be achieved with less resource-intensive, lower-emission<br />

modes of transport). Wixey’s and Lake’s article is thus a perfect concluding example of<br />

a line of argumentation that is “locked into” a particular discursive framework, i.e. their<br />

key argument is based on definitions, ideological beliefs and premises that are simply not<br />

congruent with those of alternative discursive frameworks.<br />

4.7 Addendum: The “Institutionalist” Focus on EU Space and Governance<br />

Normally, this would conclude our discussion of the different theoretical<br />

approaches to EU transport policy and planning. However, there are several researchers<br />

whom I group under the somewhat awkward sub-heading “institutionalists” whose<br />

contributions deserve at least a brief discussion at this point. These “institutionallyfocused”<br />

researchers concentrate on the central importance of Pan-European transport<br />

61 As we will see in Chapter 9, an argument made with regard to the Budapest ring road is that this EUsupported<br />

local TEN node actually benefits local and regional road traffic more than international traffic,<br />

and that instead the real sustainability problem is that the road capacity investments are not being<br />

complemented by parallel investments into rail-based public transit, thus presenting a further strategic<br />

disadvantaging of rail. Also see Lukács (2001).


171<br />

infrastructures with regard to the EU’s spatial and political integration. They believe that<br />

planning, policy concepts and institutional structures not only matter, but that they can be<br />

shaped and used proactively to positively forge cohesion and integration. Several<br />

specific sub-concerns can be distinguished. For one, most of these scholars are not so<br />

much transport specialists as political scientists and/or planning scholars working on<br />

governance issues, and they are much more concerned with long-term locational<br />

decisions than with the daily movements of goods and people. They agree that largescale<br />

transport infrastructures such as the Channel tunnel or other high-speed rail links<br />

are key re-organizers of European space that have wide-ranging political and economic<br />

consequences. But equally important to them are the locational decisions by the EU and<br />

its member governments regarding their own institutions, notably the emergence of<br />

Brussels as the “European capital” and the relocation of the German capital from Bonn to<br />

the unified <strong>Berlin</strong> (Williams 1996:93). In emphasizing the need for supranational and<br />

supra-regional planning, they also stress that European transport policy must necessarily<br />

respond to, and be guided by a European-level spatial planning framework. In this<br />

context, several spatial metaphors characterizing the new European landscape of<br />

economic power appear in the literature (see e.g. Masser, Sviden et al. 1992:25; Banister<br />

and Berechman 1993:12; Lemberg 1995:68; Kunzmann 1996; Williams 1996:96), but<br />

Nijkamp (1993:12) warns that these “creative thought experiments ... need to be<br />

substantiated with solid research and proper policy strategies.” 62<br />

Yet another, related<br />

problem with Pan-European transport planning these scholars are always conscious of<br />

62 It should be noted that in relation to the spatial metaphor of a “Northern Arc” of Europe, the<br />

corresponding Via Baltica route from <strong>Berlin</strong> to St. Petersburg was adopted as the No.1 non-EU TENextension<br />

corridor at the last Pan-European conference of Transport Ministers in Essen in 1995.


172<br />

has to do with the very institutional nature of the EU, namely its make-up of independent<br />

nation-states. Kirazidis (1994:116), for example, concludes his study on European<br />

transport as follows:<br />

The main argument of [my] book is that European transport policy rests on the<br />

national transport polices of the twelve component parts and national governments are<br />

still the pivots of political and economic activity. This does not provide an appropriate<br />

framework for resolving dilemmas in transport with respect to economic efficiency,<br />

social justice and environmental quality.<br />

Similarly, Cole and Cole (1997:174) warn that “the EC has neither the legal nor<br />

the financial instruments to guarantee the consistency and continuity of the various types<br />

of specific local aid granted in the transport infrastructure sector”. (Nijkamp and Vleugel<br />

1995:5) also point to the nationalistic and segmented character of previous European<br />

policy making, and then distinguish between reactive, demand-oriented policies where an<br />

increase in mobility is simply followed by an expansion of physical infrastructure, and<br />

proactive, supply-oriented policies where infrastructure supplies are used as a tool to<br />

manage influence and possible redirect transport demand. While clearly favoring the<br />

latter approach, they find European transport policy has so far failed to adopt this<br />

preferable approach mainly due to inertia in policy making and user behavior (i.e.<br />

continued dependence on motor vehicles). From an institutional perspective, a more<br />

long-term, pro-active approach to transport policy is therefore necessary, they argue. In<br />

the end, institutional approaches view the European project much more from a<br />

perspective of “building the European House” – a house in need of solid foundations and<br />

fixed structures. This stands in clear contrast to very liberal modernization approaches,<br />

which tend to favor additional deregulation to create a competitive, free Single European<br />

Market. In the end, however, the institutional perspective is a cross-cutting, and often


173<br />

controversial, issue, since many ecological modernization scholars would still support<br />

calls for new and improved governance structures in order to help overcome<br />

environmental challenges.<br />

4.8 Concluding Remarks<br />

The key aim of this long and wide-ranging chapter was to present a description of<br />

both the currently dominant environmental discourse of ecological modernization and of<br />

complementing and contradicting discourses shaping potential transport policy<br />

alternatives. Of course, some distinctions between the different discursive frameworks<br />

sometimes appear somewhat stereotypical, especially when common sense tells us that<br />

most of the relevant stakeholders influencing transport policy in Europe are in fact<br />

employing a mixture of the above distinguished approaches. However, I would argue<br />

that the existence of such multiple policy discourses is precisely the reason for the<br />

enormous success that the discursive framework of ecological modernization has had in<br />

shaping urban, regional, environmental and transport policy in the Europe Union:<br />

ecological modernization offers a win-win perspective that is best poised to incorporate<br />

wide-ranging environmental critiques into an overall, positive future vision of sustainable<br />

development. In his concluding paragraph, Maarten Hajer (1995:294) mused that<br />

the environmental dilemma of modern society will not go away. … It would be a great<br />

improvement if ecological politics would shed its prevailing techno-corporatist format<br />

and create open structures to determine what sort of nature and society we really want.<br />

The evidence on EU transport infrastructure investment rationales presented in the<br />

following chapters betrays Hajer’s hope: Growth and expansion-oriented discourses and<br />

techno-corporatist influences still reign strong in this particular arena.


174<br />

Printed on September 21, 2002<br />

Last revised on Sept 15, 2002<br />

PART II: RHETORIC<br />

EU Discourses on Transport Policy and<br />

Transport Infrastructure Investments


175<br />

Last modified on September 20, 2002<br />

Chapter 5:<br />

EU Discourses on Sustainable Development,<br />

Transport and Land Use<br />

.<br />

5.1 Introduction..................................................................................................... 176<br />

5.2 EU Discourses on Sustainable Development.................................................. 178<br />

5.2.1 Growth with respect for people’s needs and the environment................ 178<br />

5.2.2 From the Treaty of Rome to the 4th Environmental Action Program .... 179<br />

5.2.3 From the Maastricht Treaty to the Treaty of Amsterdam ....................... 181<br />

5.2.4 The Decision on the Review of “Towards Sustainability” ..................... 184<br />

5.2.5 The EU’s New Strategy for Sustainable Development........................... 186<br />

5.2.6 The Gothenburg European Council ........................................................ 189<br />

5.2.7 The EU White Paper on Governance...................................................... 189<br />

5.2.8 EU Input to the 2002 World Summit on Sustainable Development....... 190<br />

5.2.9 Summary Remarks and Prospects for Enlargement................................ 192<br />

5.3 EU Discourses on Sustainable Transport........................................................ 194<br />

5.3.1 The White Paper on the Common Transport Policy............................... 196<br />

5.3.2 The White Paper on Growth, Competitiveness and Employment .......... 198<br />

5.3.3 The Common Transport Policy Action Program .................................... 200<br />

5.3.4 The Communication on “Sustainable Mobility”..................................... 200<br />

5.3.5 The Green Paper on the Citizen’s Network ............................................ 201<br />

5.3.6 The White Paper on Fair Payment for Infrastructure Use ...................... 202<br />

5.3.7 Transport-specific Conclusions of the Gothenburg European Council .. 203<br />

5.3.8 The White Paper “EU Transport Policy for 2010: Time to Decide” ...... 204<br />

5.3.9 The DG TREN Website.......................................................................... 206<br />

5.3.10 Pan-European Declarations on Sustainable Transport............................ 207<br />

5.4 EU Discourses on Sustainable Urban Development....................................... 208<br />

5.4.1 The Communication “Towards an Urban Agenda in the EU” ............... 209<br />

5.4.2 Sustainable Urban Development in the EU: A Framework for Action .. 210<br />

5.4.3 The European Spatial Development Perspective.................................... 211<br />

5.4.4 The EU’s Input Papers to the 9 th UN CSD Conference in 2001............. 212<br />

5.5 The EU’s Research Frameworks: Funding for the Eco-modernist Agenda ... 213<br />

5.6 Conclusions and Open Questions ................................................................... 216


176<br />

5.1 Introduction<br />

Previous chapters have presented a comprehensive outline and overview of five<br />

different discursive frameworks for sustainable policy-making, claiming that EU policy is<br />

influenced by an eco-modernist understanding of sustainable development that avoids a<br />

radical confrontation of environmental and social issues. This chapter undertakes a more<br />

text-oriented review of the most important documents defining the EU’s understanding of<br />

sustainable development, transport and land use in order to support this claim. 1<br />

The<br />

following chapter will then present a more structural, comprehensive evaluation of the<br />

central biases apparent in EU transport policy. 2<br />

Of course, there are scores of EU documents providing definitions and inputs on<br />

the topic of sustainability and sustainable development, but not all documents carry equal<br />

weight. In this chapter, I mostly analyze official EU documents, focusing on various<br />

legally binding EU treaties and acts, on Commission White and Green Papers, as well as<br />

1 The methodology for the document review was as follows: Every paper (or webpage) was first reviewed<br />

for general content. In the vast majority of cases, the documents were available electronically (either in MS<br />

Word or Adobe PDF format), so that they could then also be systematically searched for occurrences of<br />

phrases such as “sustainable development,” “sustainability,” “transport, “mobility,” “land-use” etc. The<br />

extensive cross-referencing common in Commission materials reassured me that no crucial documents were<br />

left out of the analysis. Meanwhile, I of course did leave out scores of EU transport policy documents that<br />

are not explicitly centered around sustainability discourses – also see the note below. In addition to the<br />

actual documents, I reviewed additional press releases, supplementary materials, as well as various<br />

(supportive and antagonistic) lobby group reactions to the different Commission papers in order to<br />

supplement my own reading of the central contents with what various stakeholders had identified as its key<br />

statements. So while often starting off with very text-oriented analyses, I go beyond simple word-by-word<br />

document review in almost all individual analyses and instead strive to capture the larger discourses that<br />

emerged from a particular document.<br />

2 To clarify: Contrary to the following chapter, the focus in this chapter lies on policy documents<br />

expressing official EU rhetoric in the area of sustainability and sustainable transport and mobility. Almost<br />

by definition, a review of these documents will not necessarily be sufficient for gaining a full<br />

understanding of the conflicted general development objectives influencing EU transport infrastructure<br />

investment decisions. Not all EU transport investment decisions even pretend to address sustainability<br />

aims. This is why some of the documents analyzed in the following chapter are not discussed in this<br />

chapter and vice versa.


177<br />

on EU Research Framework Program definitions and Commission Communications.<br />

Tables 5.1 gives an overview of the key documents selected for review in this chapter. 3<br />

Table 5.1 Key EU Statements on Sustainability, Transport and Spatial Development<br />

Key statements on sustainable development and environmental policy:<br />

o Communication “Ten Years After Rio: Preparing for the WSSD” (2002)<br />

o Communication “Towards a Global Partnership for Sustainable Development” (2002)<br />

o Gothenburg European Council – Presidency Conclusions (2001)<br />

o European Union Sustainable Development Strategy – SDS (2001)<br />

o The EU White Paper on Governance (2001)<br />

o Sixth Environmental Action Program (2000-2006)<br />

o European Commission Glossary on institutions, policies and enlargement (1999)<br />

o Decision on the Review of the Fifth EAP (1998)<br />

o Treaty of Amsterdam, Article 2 (1997)<br />

o Fifth Environmental Action Program (1993-2000)<br />

o Treaty of the European Union a.k.a. Maastricht Treaty, Articles 2-6 (1992)<br />

o Fourth Environmental Action Program (1987-1992)<br />

o Single European Act, Article 130r (1986)<br />

Key EU statements on sustainable transport and sustainable mobility<br />

o White Paper on European Transport Policy for 2010 – Time to Decide (2001)<br />

o White Paper on Fair Payment for Infrastructure Use (1998)<br />

o The CTP - Sustainable Mobility: Perspectives for the Future (1998)<br />

o Green Paper on the Citizens’ Network (1996)<br />

o White Paper on Growth, Competitiveness and Employment (1993)<br />

o White Paper on the Future of the Common Transport Policy” (1992)<br />

o Green Paper on the Impact of Transport on the Environment (1992)<br />

o DG TREN webpage:<br />

http://europa.eu.int/comm/dgs/energy_transport/index_en.html<br />

Key documents on sustainable urban / spatial development and sustainable land-use:<br />

o EU Transport-Sector Input Papers to the 9 th UN CSD Conference (2001)<br />

o European Spatial Development Perspective – ESDP (1999)<br />

o Sustainable Urban Development in the EU: A Framework for Action (1998)<br />

o Communication “Towards an urban agenda in the European Union” (1997)<br />

Source: own compilation<br />

3 Note that not all of the documents received their own sub-section in this chapter. Instead, some of them<br />

are discussed in context with general developments or as lead-in/follow-up to other important documents.


178<br />

Most of these documents underwent extensive review processes within the EU,<br />

typically with repeated consultations not only between various Commission Directorate<br />

Generals but also between the Commission, the Council and the Parliament. The<br />

opportunity to carry out this particular type of analysis is especially timely. Over the<br />

course of the last few years, several crucial documents have been officially released by<br />

the Commission providing rather concise, up-to-date statements on the EU’s<br />

understanding on sustainability and transport. Most importantly, the EU released both its<br />

first-ever Sustainable Development Strategy (Commission of the European Communities<br />

2001a) and its long-awaited new White Paper on Transport in 2001 (Commission of the<br />

European Communities 2001f). Several additional papers on sustainable development<br />

were released in preparation for the UN World Summit on Sustainable Development.<br />

Additionally, I look at some more informal documents I was referred to during my<br />

investigation, including the Transport and Energy Directorate’s self-presentation on the<br />

World Wide Web.<br />

5.2 EU Discourses on Sustainable Development<br />

5.2.1 Growth with respect for people’s needs and the environment<br />

In the 1999 European Commission Glossary on institutions, policies and<br />

enlargement (Commission of the European Communities 1999a), sustainable<br />

development is defined in a typical three-dimensional manner:<br />

The concept of sustainable development refers to a form of economic growth which<br />

satisfies society's needs in terms of well-being in the short, medium and - above all -<br />

long terms. It is founded on the assumption that development must meet today's needs<br />

without jeopardising the prospects of future generations. In practical terms, it means<br />

creating the conditions for long-term economic development with due respect for the<br />

environment. The Copenhagen world summit for sustainable [correct: “social”]


179<br />

development (March 1995) stressed the need to combat social exclusion and protect<br />

public health.<br />

[Emphasis added]<br />

This definition is particularly interesting in several respects. Its middle section<br />

contains a paraphrasing of the Brundtland definition, and the last two sentences once<br />

again refer to the key dimensions of economy, environment and equity (“social<br />

exclusion”), where we find the important additions of the time and public health<br />

dimensions. Also note the interesting slip about the Copenhagen World Summit for<br />

Social Development.<br />

However, most revealing is the initial sentence, which<br />

unequivocally privileges the economic dimension by defining sustainable development as<br />

a sub-form of economic growth.<br />

This definition thus also implicitly equates<br />

“development” with “growth.” Comprised in a nutshell, we thus find the EU’s central<br />

attitude towards sustainable development as a concept that places certain (environmental<br />

and social) limitations on economic growth.<br />

5.2.2 From the Treaty of Rome to the 4th Environmental Action Program<br />

There is no mention of sustainability or environmental policy in the Treaty of<br />

Rome which established the European Economic Community (EEC) in 1957. Rather, the<br />

primary objective of the EEC was the “harmonious development of economic activities.”<br />

The first EEC environmental action program was adopted on November 22, 1973 in the<br />

wake of the first UN conference on the Human Environment in Stockholm in 1972. At<br />

this time, environmental policy making remained both closed and technocratic, and issues<br />

developed in an ad hoc and incremental fashion (Jordan 1998).


180<br />

It was the Single European Act (SEA) that provided environmental policy with a<br />

firm legal basis for action. Article 130r of the SEA sets out the following objectives:<br />

to preserve, protect and improve the quality of the environment;<br />

to contribute toward protecting human health;<br />

to ensure a prudent and rational utilization of natural resources<br />

(quoted in: Collier 1996:6)<br />

The Single European Act also introduced the polluter pays and the precautionary<br />

principles, and introduced qualified majority voting for environmental measures. 4<br />

After<br />

this, EU environmental legislation increased exponentially. For example, in the two short<br />

years between 1989 and 1991, the Environmental Council adopted more policies than it<br />

had in the 20 years before that (Jordan 1998). Following the Single European Act, the<br />

Fourth Environmental Action Program (EAP 1987-1992) marked an important shift from<br />

a sectoral approach carving up environmental issues according to various subject areas<br />

towards an integrated approach that took a more comprehensive view. It also began to<br />

focus more on the key question of implementation.<br />

4 Note that in ratifying the Rio Declaration, the EU had already de facto accepted the precautionary<br />

principle. The Rio Declaration mentions and explains the concept in the following manner:<br />

In order to protect the environment, the precautionary approach shall be widely applied by States<br />

according to their capabilities. Where there are threats of serious or irreversible damage, lack of full<br />

scientific certainty shall not be used as a reason for postponing cost-effective measures to prevent<br />

environmental degradation.<br />

The ‘polluter pays’ principle is also one of the key environmental principles of the EU Treaty. In 2000, the<br />

Commission adopted a White Paper on Environmental Liability (COM [2000] 66 final) which explores the<br />

details of how to implement the general principle, concluding that the best option was to issue a new<br />

Framework Directive on Environmental Liability. Also see<br />

http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/liability (last accessed on Jan 10, 2002). Qualified Majority Voting<br />

(QMV) is one of several formal rules of decision for the European Council, as contrasted with unanimity,<br />

simple majority voting, or the co-decision procedure which includes the parliament. Decision rules have<br />

been amended several times in successive treaty reforms. However, even in the latter revisions to Article<br />

130r in the Maastricht Treaty, several significant areas of policy making remained exempted from QMV,<br />

among them fiscal, town, country and land use planning, as well as energy measures (see Collier 1996:6).


181<br />

5.2.3 From the Maastricht Treaty to the Treaty of Amsterdam<br />

Despite these important steps forward, sustainable development was still not yet<br />

fully mainstreamed into EU policy. In the 1992 Treaty on European Union (TEU, or<br />

Maastricht Treaty) the concept of sustainability is mentioned in the first substantial<br />

paragraph, but, consistent with the glossary definition, the concept remains framed in a<br />

context of economic growth, thus leaving issues of deep ecological challenges and social<br />

conflict to be fought out in other arenas. The exact wording of Article 2 of the TEU is as<br />

follows:<br />

The Community shall have as its task […] to promote throughout the Community a<br />

harmonious, balanced and sustainable development of economic activities, a high<br />

level of employment and of social protection, equality between men and women,<br />

sustainable and non-inflationary growth, a high degree of competitiveness and<br />

convergence of economic performance, a high level of protection and improvement of<br />

the quality of the environment, the raising of the standard of living and quality of life<br />

and economic and social cohesion and solidarity among Member States.”<br />

[my emphasis]<br />

In Article 3 of the Maastricht Treaty, the EU sets out a series of policy goals for<br />

itself, three of which are of particular relevance to this study:<br />

[T]he activities of the Community shall include …:<br />

(f) a common transport policy<br />

…<br />

(k) the strengthening of economic and social cohesion<br />

(l) a policy in the sphere of the environment<br />

Additionally, Article 6 of the Maastricht Treaty demands the following:<br />

Environmental protection requirements must be integrated into the definition and<br />

implementation of the Community polices and activities referred to in Article 3, in<br />

particular with a view to promoting sustainable development.


182<br />

This article is frequently quoted by environmental groups working on both<br />

transport and other substantive areas of EU policy such as market integration,<br />

employment, or agriculture to point out that the EU is acting in violation of the<br />

Maastricht Treaty whenever serious environmental protection requirements are ignored.<br />

It was left to the Fifth Environmental Action Programme (EAP) of the EU to<br />

more clearly define the community’s commitment to sustainable development. EAPs had<br />

already been a key feature of EU environmental policy since the early 1970s. The Fifth<br />

EAP covered the period from 1993 to 2000. Tellingly entitled “Towards Sustainability,”<br />

the program provides the following, rather traditional definition of sustainability :<br />

the word 'sustainable' is intended to reflect a policy and strategy for the continued<br />

economic and social development without detriment to the environment and the<br />

natural resources on the quality of which continued human activity and further<br />

development depend. [my emphasis]<br />

The Fifth Action Program signaled the Commission’s move away from a more<br />

traditional “command and control” approach to environmental protection towards the use<br />

of new instruments such as eco-audits, eco-labels, voluntary agreements and even<br />

variants of eco-taxes, which can be summarized under the heading of “new marketinformation-based<br />

elements” (Sbragia 2000:315).<br />

In 1995, the European Environment Agency presented a rather critical report on<br />

the state of Europe’s environment (European Environment Agency 1995), making it clear<br />

that even increases and advances in environmental protection are no guarantors for a<br />

move towards sustainable development: “The EU is making progress in reducing certain<br />

pressure on the environment, though this is not enough to improve the general quality of<br />

the environment and even less to progress towards sustainable development” (EEA, 1995<br />

as quoted in Collier not dated).


183<br />

The 1997 Treaty of Amsterdam (ToA) then produced several important<br />

amendments and revisions to the Treaty on European Union and made an even stronger<br />

commitment to sustainability by explicitly and unequivocally referring to the principle of<br />

sustainable development in its preamble and then calling for sustainable development in<br />

its first substantive paragraph. Compare Article 2 of the 1992 Maastricht Treaty with<br />

Article 2 of the 1997 Amsterdam Treaty:<br />

The Union shall have as its basis the following objectives:<br />

- to promote economic and social progress and a high level of employment and to<br />

achieve balanced and sustainable development, in particular through the creation of an<br />

area without internal frontiers, through the strengthening of economic and social<br />

cohesion and through the establishment of economic and monetary union […].<br />

[Emphasis added]<br />

Particularly noteworthy is the conspicuous absence of the term “economic<br />

growth” in the formulation of both this and the four other objectives. The term<br />

“progress” fills in the blank here. Also of interest is the mention of the problematic term<br />

“cohesion” next to the calls for market integration and monetary union. 5<br />

Following the 1992 UN Conference on Environment and Development (UNCED,<br />

or ‘Rio Earth Summit’), the EU has been one of the most committed governments with<br />

regard to promoting Agenda 21, which, together with the Rio Declaration, was the major<br />

outcome of this international conference. Just in time for the Earth Summit, the<br />

Commission also published a “Green Paper on Transport and the Environment” designed<br />

to reflect the EU’s growing concern about transport’s impact on the greenhouse effect<br />

and rising CO2 emissions (Commission of the European Communities 1992a). While<br />

transport’s role in global environmental deterioration is thus widely acknowledged,<br />

Agenda 21 still did not include a separate chapter on transport to reflect its importance.<br />

5 Note that a more extensive discussion of the controversial term is provided in later chapters.


184<br />

However, energy – easily one of the most controversial topics both during the Rio<br />

Summit and in the ensuing string of UN Conferences on Climate Change and Sustainable<br />

Development - also did not receive its own chapter. The obvious explanation here is that<br />

in view of the persistent disagreements on global energy or transport policy matters, the<br />

drafters of Agenda 21 and its subsequent documents preferred to conceal this<br />

embarrassing fact by mainstreaming the topics under different headings.<br />

In the last few years, partly in light of the five-year review of the Rio Summit, the<br />

EU has presented several important documents with regard to sustainable development.<br />

Two key documents, the 1998 Decision on the Review of the Fifth EAP and the EU's<br />

New Sustainable Development Strategy (SDS) both assign particular relevance to the<br />

transport sector. They therefore deserve a quick introduction:<br />

5.2.4 The Decision on the Review of “Towards Sustainability”<br />

The Fifth EAP provided for a review of its measures and actions to be undertaken<br />

before the end of 1995. With the 1998 Decision, the EU, somewhat belatedly, reacted to<br />

this provision as well as the EAA's Dobris Assessment on Europe's environment<br />

(European Environment Agency 1995) and the Commission's own progress report on the<br />

Fifth EAP. Additionally, since both the adoption of Agenda 21 internationally, and the<br />

adoption of the EU's White Paper on Growth, Competitiveness and Employment<br />

happened after the adoption of the 5 th EAP, the Commission decided that a clearer<br />

definition of key priorities and issues for the remaining two years of the EAP was needed<br />

to speed up the EAP's objectives.


185<br />

The 1998 Decision is particularly relevant in that transport, together with<br />

agriculture, energy, industry, and tourism, was one of five chosen “target sectors” whose<br />

selection was to give “additional impetus” to the implementation in the two remaining<br />

years of the program. While this is certainly commendable, actual listed priority<br />

objectives within the transport sector were rather pedestrian and largely repeated previous<br />

eco-modernist commitments and sound bites, e.g. “tighten provisions on emissions and<br />

noise,” “achieve better internalisation of external costs in transport prices,” “promoting a<br />

more integrated transport policy,” “better integration of land-use and transportation,”<br />

“promoting demand-management measures,” “facilitating intermodality,” or<br />

“encouraging public and/or collective transport and low-emission vehicles.” However,<br />

the decision also mentioned the concrete aim to reduce the imbalances between different<br />

transport modes by developing methodologies for Strategic Environmental Assessment<br />

(SEA) 6 for the TENs and for corridor analysis. This concrete aim eventually translated<br />

into several pilot studies in that area, as well as an entire handbook on SEA. However, to<br />

date, there has been no SEA performed on either the TENs or TINA (also see Chapter 7).<br />

Remarkably, the Decision does not contain a single mention of (the need to<br />

promote) non-motorized transport, and apart from cursory mentions of the need to favor<br />

public transport, the transport priority section is entirely silent on the topic of urban<br />

transport. This is especially surprising given the fact that in a later section on priority<br />

issue areas, Article 10 on the “promotion of local and regional initiatives” specifically<br />

mentions that “particular attention will be given to [...] (b) developing a comprehensive<br />

6 SEAs are sometimes also called Strategic Environmental Impact Assessments (SEIAs). SEA is the more<br />

commonly used acronym that is used throughout this study. The actual phrase used in the decision is more<br />

already cautious not to demand outright that an SEA on the TENs be performed - a long-term demand of<br />

environmental NGOs - but rather aims at “developing potential methods of analysis with a view to strategic<br />

evaluation of the environmental impact of the trans-European transport network.” Also see Chapter 7.


186<br />

approach to urban issues ..., and (c) promoting the exchange of experience between local<br />

authorities in relation to sustainable transport initiatives.”<br />

5.2.5 The EU’s New Strategy for Sustainable Development<br />

Just in time for the Gothenburg Summit in June 2001, the Commission presented<br />

the Communication “A Sustainable Europe for a Better World: A European Union<br />

Strategy for Sustainable Development” (Commission of the European Communities<br />

2001a, henceforth abbreviated SDS). With this Communication, the Commission<br />

responded to the European Council request at the 1999 Helsinki Summit “to prepare a<br />

proposal for a long-term strategy dovetailing policies for economically, socially and<br />

ecologically sustainable development to be presented to the European Council in June<br />

2001” (p.2). In between Helsinki and Gothenburg, the Lisbon Summit had somewhat<br />

amended the task by setting a new strategic goal for the Union “to become the most<br />

competitive and dynamic knowledge-based economy in the world capable of sustainable<br />

economic growth with more and better jobs and greater social cohesion.” Thus, it was<br />

clear that the key EU development themes of the last few years, i.e. competition, growth,<br />

information economy, employment and cohesion, all had to be worked into the SDS.<br />

The SDS itself is a remarkable document in several respects. After a few<br />

predictable introductory remarks with bold-printed reminders of how “economic growth,<br />

social cohesion and environmental protection must go hand in hand” and of how<br />

sustainable development offers a “positive long-term vision,” we find already the first<br />

new important development theme on the first page: the call for “decoupling<br />

environmental degradation and resource consumption from economic and social


187<br />

developments.” This de-coupling theme has emerged with particular force in the<br />

transport sector, where discussions on de-coupling additional growth in transport activity<br />

from economic growth has emerged as a new principal goal of European transport policy<br />

(also see below).<br />

The SDS subsequently identifies six major threats to sustainable development.<br />

For two of them, “combating poverty and social exclusion,” and the “dealing with the<br />

economic and social implication of an aging of the society” the SDS refrains from<br />

proposing any new actions and measures since recent European Councils at Lisbon, Nice<br />

and Stockholm supposedly already addressed these sufficiently. The four remaining<br />

priorities, for which new measures and actions are proposed, are as follows:<br />

?? Limit climate change and increase the use of clean energy<br />

?? Address threats to public health<br />

?? Manage natural resources more responsibly<br />

?? Improve the transport system and land-use management<br />

With regard to the first commitment, the EU thinks out loud beyond Kyoto (its<br />

commitment to which the Union renews), aiming for a reduction in atmospheric<br />

greenhouse gas emissions by an average of 1 percent per year over 1990 levels up to<br />

2020. Moreover, the EU aims for a 7 percent share of alternative fuels for all cars and<br />

trucks by 2010 and at least 20 percent by 2020, with a proposal to be adopted by the<br />

Commission in 2005 (see p.10).<br />

As for transport sector proposals, the aim to decouple transport growth from GDP<br />

growth is stated as the first headline objective, complemented with a concrete proposal to<br />

shift from road to rail, water and public transport “so that the share of road transport in


188<br />

2010 is no greater than in 1998” (p.12). Other noteworthy elements are the already<br />

previously announced revision of the guidelines for the (financing of) the TENs, due for<br />

proposal in 2001, and a “marked reduction in the share of finance given to road<br />

transport.” Teleworking is also to be promoted. Even more interestingly, the<br />

Commission proposes to “assess the coherence of the zoning of different Community<br />

policies,” which responds to criticisms that geographical eligibility criteria for<br />

Community funding programs often seem illogical, outdated or simply inappropriate. As<br />

far as spatial policies are concerned, the SDS simply refers to and re-endorses the<br />

European Spatial Development Perspective (ESDP) and avoids any clarification of the<br />

problem of rural-urban divides by simultaneously proposing to both “diversify income<br />

sources in rural areas” and “encourage local initiatives to tackle the problems faced by<br />

urban areas” (all quotes from p. 13). Among the provisions for the implementation and<br />

review of the SDS are the proposal to establish a ‘Sustainable Development Round Table'<br />

of 10 independent high-level experts and plans to hold a two-yearly Stakeholder Forum.<br />

As might be expected, reactions to the SDS have been mixed. In an Open Letter,<br />

the Green G8, i.e. the eight largest environmental NGOs in Europe, released a concise<br />

ten-point statement that welcome many of the elements in the strategy, particularly the<br />

intention to progressively decouple resource use from economic growth, costing polluting<br />

and removing ‘perverse subsidies,’ including in the transport sector (BirdLife<br />

International, Climate Network Europe et al. May 29, 2001). However, the NGOs also<br />

contend that the global dimension of the SDS remains weak, that consultation was<br />

marginal and that there is no clear indication in the strategy of what constitutes firm<br />

policy commitments and what general policy aspirations.<br />

Predictably, the


189<br />

environmentalists also strongly reject the strategy’s intention to support research, and<br />

development of technology related to nuclear energy (or rather: nuclear waste).<br />

5.2.6 The Gothenburg European Council<br />

The Gothenburg European Council in June 2001 “agreed on a strategy for<br />

sustainable development” (p.1) and, congruent with the SDS, selected four policy priority<br />

areas in which to develop guiding measures and objectives: climate change, transport,<br />

public health, and natural resources. Yet once again, the EU’s discourse is steeped in an<br />

industry-friendly, technology-oriented rhetoric that emphasizes the win-win character of<br />

integrating sustainability objectives into policy-making. The presidency conclusions do,<br />

however, also reemphasize the necessity to achieve economic growth without<br />

proportional increases in resource use (European Union 2001:4):<br />

Clear and stable objectives for sustainable development will present significant<br />

economic opportunities. This has the potential to unleash a new wave of technological<br />

innovation and<br />

investment, generating growth and employment. The European Council invites<br />

industry to take part in the development and wider use of new environmentally<br />

friendly technologies in sectors such as energy and transport. In this context the<br />

European Council stresses the importance of decoupling economic growth from<br />

resource use.<br />

The transport-specific conclusions of this important Council are described in section<br />

5.3. below.<br />

5.2.7 The EU White Paper on Governance<br />

The new EU White Paper on European Governance (Commission of the European<br />

Communities 2001h) puts forth five general principles for good, democratic governance<br />

in the EU which can be seen as stand-ins for what is usually considered “social


190<br />

sustainability” in the widest sense: openness, participation, accountability, effectiveness<br />

and coherence. The White Paper rarely uses the terms “sustainable” or “sustainability,”<br />

however, and these references always links back to the Sustainable Development<br />

Strategy. Yet there is one passage on policy coherence which makes direct reference to<br />

transport and land use questions, emphasizing the need for enhanced dialogue between<br />

different levels of government (p.13):<br />

The territorial impacts of EU policies in areas such as transport, energy or<br />

environment should be addressed. These policies should form part of a coherent<br />

whole as stated in the EU’s second cohesion report; there is a need to avoid a logic<br />

which is too sector-specific. In the same way, decisions taken at regional and local<br />

levels should be coherent with a broader set of principles that would underpin more<br />

sustainable and balanced territorial development within the Union.<br />

Sustainability is thus also seen as having a strong institutional dimension.<br />

5.2.8 EU Input to the 2002 World Summit on Sustainable Development<br />

The EU released several papers in preparation of the UN World Summit on<br />

Sustainable Development in Johannesburg (August 24 th<br />

– September 4 th 2002). A<br />

special webpage documenting the EU’s input and involvement in the WSSD<br />

(http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/wssd/index_en.html) was created presenting the<br />

by-now typical, massive onslaught of downloadable related EU speeches, press releases,<br />

fact sheets, reports, glossy brochures and other background materials, including the SDS<br />

itself. Two Commission Communications summarize the EU’s approach to the WSSD.<br />

Both are extremely broad in their agendas. The transport sector receives numerous<br />

mentions in both documents, but neither one assigns an especially privileged role to the<br />

sector. 7<br />

This is not surprising in light of the fact that the WSSD agenda itself does not<br />

7 The first Communication, released in February 2001 (Commission of the European Communities 2001o),<br />

sets out four broad strategic objectives (“increased global equity and an effective partnership;” “better


191<br />

directly focus on transport issues. Instead, the WSSD plenary sessions are organized<br />

around the six topics “health,” “biodiversity/ecosystems,” “agriculture,” “cross-sectoral<br />

issues” (e.g. trade, technology, consumptions patterns, education), “water/sanitation,” and<br />

“energy.” In the end, both the various EU contributions and the overall agenda of the<br />

WSSD once again demonstrate that, ten years after the Rio Earth Summit, the term<br />

“sustainable development” has largely lost its environmental(ist) focus and is now used<br />

as a stand-in for any type of “good” development.<br />

Interestingly, on the new WSSD-related EU website, one also finds a section on<br />

“Frequently Asked Questions about the EU and its position on the World Summit on<br />

Sustainable Development.” After presenting a slightly modified Brundtland definition,<br />

the first question, “What is sustainable development?” is answered as follows:<br />

Sustainable development focuses on improving the quality of life for all citizens<br />

without increasing the use of natural resources beyond the capacity of the environment<br />

to supply them indefinitely. … It is about taking action, changing policy and practice<br />

at all levels, from the individual to the international. Sustainable development is not a<br />

new idea. Many cultures over the course of human history have recognised the need<br />

for harmony between the environment, society and economy. It is the articulation of<br />

these ideas in the context of a global industrial and information society that is new.<br />

There is an important horizontal nature of the sustainable development challenge: it is<br />

not something you can neatly put into boxes - economic, social, environmental - and<br />

then deal with each box individually. The links between the three main pillars of<br />

sustainable development must be addressed. 8<br />

integration and coherence at the international level;” “adoption of environment and development targets;”<br />

and “more effective action at national level and international monitoring,” see p.2) and four key issues<br />

(“protecting the natural resources base of economic development;” “integrating environment and poverty<br />

eradication;” “making globalization sustainable;” and “enhancing good governance and participation,” see<br />

p.3). The second Communication (Commission of the European Communities 2002b), released a year<br />

later, is organized around six themes: “harnessing globalization: trade for sustainable development,”<br />

“fighting poverty and promoting social development,” “sustainable management of natural and<br />

environmental resources,” “improving the coherence of European Union policies,” “better governance at all<br />

levels,” and “financing sustainable development.”<br />

8 See http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/wssd/qa_general_en.html#1, last accessed Aug. 16, 2002.


192<br />

The acknowledgement that “harmony between environment, society and<br />

economy” is not easily ascertained “in the context of a global industrial and information<br />

society” is noteworthy, as is the parallel dismissal of a sectoralized approach to<br />

sustainability.<br />

5.2.9 Summary Remarks and Prospects for Enlargement<br />

Overall, it should be noted that within different EU documents, one can discern a<br />

non-incidental, recurring distinction between the terms “sustainable growth” as it appears<br />

in the Maastricht Treaty and also frequently in DG Transport and Energy documents, and<br />

“sustainable development”, which is the more inclusive term, typically used in all DG<br />

Environment documents, and more recently in the SDS. Interestingly, the Amsterdam<br />

Treaty speaks of both “sustainable development of economic activities” and of<br />

“sustainable growth” (also see Collier 1999:85).<br />

Of course, despite being a relatively successful area of EU policy-making at least<br />

in terms of the amount of legislation passed, environmental policy has often been<br />

overshadowed by discussions on other all-encompassing topics such as competitiveness,<br />

enlargement, subsidiarity and governance and democracy. Jordan (1998) identifies two<br />

significant shortcomings of EU environmental policy. On one hand, there is an<br />

implementation gap, which calls attention to the fact that especially in the early days,<br />

much EU legislation was not appropriately enforced in the member states. On the other<br />

hand, there is an integration gap, meaning that environmental considerations have not<br />

been successfully integrated into all other areas of EU policy-making. An obvious<br />

example is the EU agricultural policy, which has stimulated overproduction of unneeded


193<br />

foods and subsidized intensive farming methods whose fertilizers have been harmful to<br />

natural soils and polluted groundwater reserves. We will see that EU transport policy has<br />

been equally unsuccessful in consistently protecting the environment. Nevertheless, the<br />

need for the integration and mainstreaming of environmental aspects is being repeated<br />

almost like a mantra in all recent environmental and transport policy documents.<br />

Eastern enlargement will most certainly be the biggest challenge to EU<br />

environmental policy in the coming decades, and transport is a major aspect of that<br />

challenge. Although an impressive amount of the CEEC legislation has already been<br />

brought into compliance with EU laws and standards, this compliance presently largely<br />

exists on paper. A frequent excuse is cost. Pollution prevention is to a large extent seen<br />

as a matter of being able to invest in newer and cleaner infrastructures and technologies,<br />

especially in areas such as waste water treatment or energy production. Nevertheless,<br />

deficiencies in environmental protection, in the CEE states as well as in many of the EU’s<br />

current member states, have more to do with non-enforcement, political unwillingness to<br />

promote unpopular measures (such as restrictions on motor vehicle use) and a general<br />

lack of awareness on ecological matters. The SDS includes a specific section on<br />

enlargement, which includes the interesting observation that the future Member States<br />

have much richer biodiversity that current ones. The strategy further calls for an active<br />

integration of the Candidate countries in the implementation of the strategy (see p.9).<br />

Note that the EU Commission is currently preparing its Sixth Environmental<br />

Action Program (EAP, also see Chapter 4) and a new Green Paper on Urban Transport.<br />

Overall, the new EAP proposal contained little innovative language, and most of the<br />

concrete actions proposed are in the realm of more studies, reports, or best practice


194<br />

documentations. Moreover, the extremely vague and non-committal definition of<br />

sustainable development provided in the original proposal for the Sixth EAP is somewhat<br />

indicative of the overall de-evolution of the connotations of the term “sustainable<br />

development”:<br />

A prudent use of the world’s natural resources and the protection of the global<br />

ecosystem are a condition for sustainable development, together with economic<br />

prosperity and a balanced social development. Sustainable development is concerned<br />

with our long-term welfare here in Europe and at the global level and with the<br />

heritage we leave to our children and grandchildren.<br />

(CEC 2001c:11, my emphasis)<br />

Thus, certain ecological, economical and social aspects are now defined as a<br />

condition, not a defining feature of sustainable development, which now appears as<br />

connected to the two rather innocuous terms “welfare” and “heritage” with an important<br />

focus on global reach.<br />

5.3 EU Discourses on Sustainable Transport<br />

Generally speaking, the use of the terms “sustainable transport” or “sustainable<br />

mobility” has been quite inflationary in EU documents in recent years, with almost<br />

every form and mode of transport from bicycling to driving to maritime shipping to<br />

aviation suddenly being labeled “sustainable.” Typically this occurs by talking of<br />

sustainable mobility rather than sustainable transport. Many scholars, and especially<br />

environmental NGOs, have pointed out that by putting the emphasis on “sustainable<br />

mobility” rather than on “sustainable transport,” the EU often ignores or neglects another<br />

major issue in transport, namely accessibility. In emphasizing mobility one assumes the<br />

need to travel as given, thereby implicitly establishing mobility as a goal in and of itself


195<br />

(as opposed to viewing transport as a means to an end). Also, while non-motorized<br />

transport, public transit and rail are still referred to as “more” sustainable, few EU<br />

documents categorize automobile or plane travel as outright unsustainable. Some even<br />

do the opposite. For example, under the heading “Efficient and Sustainable Use of the<br />

Infrastructure”, the European Spatial Development Perspective (ESDP) 9 concludes that<br />

“in sparsely populated peripheral regions … regional air transport, including short-haul<br />

services, has to be given priority.” Baeten (2000:71) summarized EU transport policy<br />

goals as follows:<br />

?? Spatial planning to reduce transport demand and create opportunities for<br />

alternative transport modes;<br />

?? Construction of new infrastructures;<br />

?? Improvement of public transport;<br />

?? Technical improvement of cars and fuels;<br />

?? Measures to induce changing travel behaviour;<br />

?? [Endorsement of] the polluter pays principle. For transport policies, this means<br />

that ‘external costs’ such as air pollution or congestion have to be integrated<br />

into total pricing of transport generated by road users<br />

He then argues that<br />

It is immediately clear from these EC transport policy goals that the Commission<br />

relies upon well-tested policy options which were common sense even before the<br />

notion of sustainable transport came into vogue. Moreover, this commitment is so<br />

vague that is [sic] does not curtail any traditional planning option, including the<br />

construction of new roads.<br />

While generally sympathetic to Baeten’s criticisms, I would argue that<br />

introducing the notion of sustainable transport into EU policy has nevertheless had an<br />

impact on at least the formulation of environmental policy goals. Also, as we will see in<br />

later sections of this study, different parts of the Commission pursue different goals, use<br />

9 Note that although published by the Commission, the ESDP is not an official EU document, but rather a<br />

document agreed at the Informal Council of Ministers responsible for Spatial Planning (Potsdam, 1999).


196<br />

different rhetoric, and propagate different paths of implementation. In the end, I am not<br />

content with a general critique of EU transport policy that simply states the<br />

transformation and cooptation of sustainability arguments as a fact. Instead, I am<br />

interested in uncovering the details of this transformation. As a first contribution towards<br />

this aim, the following section takes a closer look at specific sustainable transport and<br />

mobility references in some key EU policy statements.<br />

5.3.1 The White Paper on the Common Transport Policy<br />

This important 1992 White Paper (Commission of the European Communities<br />

1992c) provided the basis for EU transport policy throughout the 1990s, and in particular<br />

for the Action Program on the CTP (Commission of the European Communities 1998g).<br />

It identified serious imbalances in Europe’s transport system, noting that road freight was<br />

now almost double its 1970 volume, with road transport now accounting for 70% of all<br />

transport activity (§ 14). The paper called for an “integrated approach to sustainable<br />

mobility.” However, the crucial term “sustainable mobility” is never concretely defined<br />

in the entire 123 page document. It is vaguely defined it as “efficient, safe transport<br />

under the best possible environmental and social conditions” (§123, also see §38-40) but<br />

the paper ultimately falls short of a truly new, original approach to EU transport<br />

development in several ways. The limits for environmental maneuvering are always<br />

clearly delineated. For example, the “trends and tendencies” section concludes that<br />

“transport is a growth industry” (§ 10), and instead of a commitment to reduce transport<br />

volumes, one finds then references to accommodate transport growth (§12). The paper<br />

even admits that “the risk of the development of the transport sector being unsustainable


197<br />

in the medium to long term due to its broad environmental impact remains real” (§28).<br />

Meanwhile, the first item on the Commission’s global program for sustainable mobility is<br />

“the continued reinforcement and proper functioning of the internal market facilitating<br />

the free movement of goods and persons throughout the Community” (§40a). Overall,<br />

the White Paper’s mainstream, eco-modernist faith in win-win solutions is best captured<br />

in §92, where the Commission finally concludes that<br />

The challenge for the Community’s transport system is how to provide, in the most<br />

efficient manner, the services that are necessary for the continued success of the single<br />

market and the mobility of the individual traveler, while continuing to reduce the<br />

inefficiencies and imbalances of the system and safeguarding against the harmful<br />

effects that increase transport activity generates. It is possible to meet this challenge,<br />

while respecting the basic tenets of the free market, by the introduction of<br />

economically efficient transport policies. [Emphasis added]<br />

Bowers (1992), who provided a useful, environmentally-oriented section-bysection<br />

explication of the White Paper, points out that “the bicycle [side by side with the<br />

electric car] finally gets a mention in §176, but walking is never mentioned as a means of<br />

transport.” In the road sector, the Commission places much optimism in new pricing<br />

mechanisms (see §76), thus already foreshadowing elements of the 1998 White Paper on<br />

infrastructure pricing (see below). Similarly, the documents makes repeated references to<br />

the “Citizen’s Network” and other planned initiatives.<br />

However, the paper also addresses the key environmental problems of “energy<br />

consumption and operational pollution,” “congestion,” “land-use” and “carriage of<br />

dangerous goods” and explicitly discusses reactions to the Commission’s previously<br />

published Green Paper on Transport and Environment (Commission of the European<br />

Communities 1992a). Here, two quotes are important to keep in mind for later sections of<br />

this study. First, the White Paper notes that “although land-use and spatial planning are


198<br />

primarily a national and/or local matter, there is a Community dimension.” Secondly, we<br />

find a surprisingly engaged call to “take [twofold] action in order to deal more<br />

specifically with the congestion caused by the use of the private car [through the]<br />

promotion of collective and environmentally friendly modes of transport and at the same<br />

time the dissuasion of private car use” (§174, for additional details see §175-177). Note<br />

that this is a rather different discourse from the infrastructure expansion-oriented anticongestion<br />

rhetoric which we will find in both the 1993 White Paper on Growth and the<br />

2001 White Paper on Transport (see below).<br />

Finally, the 1992 White Paper of course also dedicated numerous paragraphs to<br />

the establishment and development of the Trans-European Networks (TENs). By then,<br />

the creation, upgrading, expansion and optimization of the TENs had emerged as one of<br />

the most hotly debated issues within the challenge of creating an ever-expanding<br />

(sustainable?) Europe. The same TENs also played a key role in another key<br />

Commission White Paper on competition and growth released only a year later.<br />

Although not a transport policy paper per se, this influential paper nevertheless deserves<br />

a quick glance.<br />

5.3.2 The White Paper on Growth, Competitiveness and Employment<br />

The EU White Paper on Growth, Competitiveness and Employment contains two<br />

major sections that refer to the TENs. The document is listed here not because these<br />

sections contain particularly interesting references to sustainable transport but because of<br />

the complete and utter absence of the concept of sustainability in the document. This


199<br />

document stands out in that it is steeped in competitive language that presents transport<br />

networks as “the lifeblood of EU competitiveness:”<br />

Traffic jams are not only exasperating, they also cost Europe dear in terms of<br />

productivity. Bottlenecks and missing links in the infrastructure fabric; lack of<br />

interoperability between modes and systems. Networks are the arteries of the single<br />

market. They are the life blood of competitiveness, and their malfunction is reflected<br />

in lost opportunities to create new markets and hence in a level of job creation that<br />

falls short of our potential.<br />

(Commission of the European Communities 1993:Section 3.1) 10<br />

This document is light-years away from the EU’s current SDS that calls for a<br />

decoupling of transport and GDP growth. Arguing quite the contrary, this White Paper<br />

argues that “by developing the movement of people and goods Europe has been able to<br />

marry economic prosperity, quality of life and commercial efficiency” (CEC 1993,<br />

Development Theme II, p.1). The gist of this White Paper is that faster and more travel is<br />

unequivocally better – better for economic development and better for the EU.<br />

Environmental and safety concerns appear as but an afterthought. In the section<br />

‘Development Theme II: Trans-European transport and energy networks – Why?’ the<br />

Commission placed the following framed sentence in special print: “Making traffic<br />

faster, safer and more environmentally compatible, facilitating and boosting trade, and<br />

bringing Member States closer to their Eastern and Southern neighbours would herald the<br />

advent of the European Union..” Clearly, speed, increased trade and connectivity are key<br />

themes in this paper. In sum, the paper is remarkable mainly in its lack of sustainability<br />

rhetoric just one year after the Rio Earth Summit.<br />

10 The online version of the document is divided into several html files that are each individually numbered.<br />

See http://www.europa.eu.int/en/record/white/c93700/ch02_1.html


200<br />

5.3.3 The Common Transport Policy Action Program<br />

From 1995 to 2000, the Common Transport Policy was enacted via an Action<br />

Program which was organized around strategic objectives concerning market<br />

liberalization; improved integration of transport systems across Europe; fair and efficient<br />

pricing within and between transport modes, and an enhanced social dimension. After<br />

the first two paragraphs, the term “sustainability” never again appears in the document,<br />

and there are few explicit references to environmental matters. One notable exception is<br />

the summary section III A 2, where under the heading “Environment,” we suddenly find<br />

a short statement that “strategic environment assessment of the Trans-European network<br />

will be important for decisions about individual projects.” There is, however, no context<br />

provided for this claim.<br />

5.3.4 The Communication on “Sustainable Mobility”<br />

In December 1998, the Commission published its Communication “Sustainable<br />

Mobility – Perspectives for the Future” (Commission of the European Communities<br />

1998g) in which the Commission reviewed the performance of the Action Program and<br />

laid out its future approach. The communications insists that “the principles established<br />

in 1995 should remain the basis for completing the CTP” (p.10) and then proceeds to set<br />

out an ambitious updated action program covering all aspects of transportation. Almost<br />

half, namely nine of the 20 pages in the Communication are dedicated to a two annexes<br />

that list the Commission’s main actions for the period 1998 to 2000 and possible<br />

proposed tasks up to 2004. Both the annexes and the document body are somewhat<br />

rigidly organized around the three goals of “improving efficiency and competitiveness,”


201<br />

improving quality,” and “improving external effectiveness.” The term “sustainability” is<br />

rather extensively used in body of the Communication, especially in the sub-headings on<br />

environment. In particular, the Communication insists that<br />

The development of transport systems must not be at the expense of the quality of life<br />

of citizens or the destruction of the environment. The indefinite continuation of current<br />

trends in transport in certain modes (road, air) would be unsustainable in relation to its<br />

environmental impact, in particular as regards climate change. The development of<br />

sustainable forms of transport is therefore one of the key priorities of the Commission.<br />

[p. 7, emphasis in the original.]<br />

Ultimately, however, the new program is as ambitious as it is non-committal in<br />

terms of true priority setting. Issues of market access, systems integration, pricing and<br />

technological upgrading feature somewhat too comfortably next to questions of<br />

environmental protection and climate change. The difficult relationship between<br />

transport and urban and regional development is also not tackled head-on, but at least<br />

mentioned as an area worthy of further investigation. 11<br />

5.3.5 The Green Paper on the Citizen’s Network<br />

The EU Green Paper “The Citizen’s Network” (Commission of the European<br />

Communities 1996a) was mostly focused on the promotion of public transport in urban<br />

areas. In the document, the Commission promises a refocusing of its research and<br />

11 Regarding the ESDP, the Communication notes that “an examination will be needed of the Common<br />

Transport Policy in relation to the evolving European Spatial Development Perspective” (p.9, emphasis in<br />

the original). No specific Communication on Transport and the ESDP exists, however. Regarding<br />

economic and social cohesion, the Communication notes the following (p.5):<br />

Efficient and sustainable transport systems play a key role in regional development. Structural policies<br />

and the CTP complement one another and therefore promote a more balanced and sustainable<br />

development of the Union's territory, particularly by improving accessibility and the situation of weaker<br />

regions and disadvantaged social groups. The Commission will set out how these two policies can<br />

achieve maximum synergies in a communication on Transport and Cohesion.<br />

For further details on the notion of “cohesion” and the Commission’s important 1998 Communication on<br />

Transport and Cohesion, see Chapter 6.


202<br />

development work on transport towards policies and programs that improve public<br />

transport and promote door-to-door service. The executive summary specifically talks<br />

about the relationship between public transport networks and the TENs, calling them the<br />

basis for a network “which is environmentally sustainable.” Specifically, the Green<br />

Paper claims the following:<br />

The TENs obviously related to long distance links, but equally clearly these long<br />

distance routes must link into local transport systems. The Commission will favor<br />

those TENs links which interconnect with local systems and which promote public<br />

transport.<br />

(Commission of the European Communities 1996a, Executive Summary)<br />

As we will see in later chapters, this claim stands in direct contrast to EU-related<br />

funding in the case of the Central Eastern Europe candidate states in general, and the case<br />

of ring road funding in particular. The most significant current grant source of transport<br />

infrastructure funding in CEE is ISPA, and ISPA specifically focuses on TEN priority<br />

corridors in the road and rail sectors but it thereby explicitly excludes public transport. In<br />

the particular case of Budapest, detailed in Chapter 8, the M0 ring road provides a classic<br />

example of a road infrastructure that indeed interconnects with local transport systems,<br />

but which, by receiving large sums of international funding from the EU and its related<br />

funding institutions (in this case the EIB), is further accelerating car use and inducing<br />

sprawl, putting local transit systems at a further disadvantage.<br />

5.3.6 The White Paper on Fair Payment for Infrastructure Use<br />

Many of the key contents in this paper already appeared in the controversial 1995<br />

Green Paper on Fair and Efficient Pricing (Commission of the European Communities<br />

1995). The premise of this important White Paper is that “the great diversity of


203<br />

infrastructure charging systems across modes of transport and Member States undermines<br />

the efficiency and the sustainability of Europe’s transport system” (§1, Executive<br />

Summary). The key proposition of the paper is to introduce the marginal social cost<br />

charging principle to “enhance both the efficiency and the sustainability of the transport<br />

system” (§3, executive summary). The paper is quite indicative for the Commission’s<br />

eco-modernist rhetoric on sustainable transport in the sense that it aims to set a new<br />

agenda for the removal of current biases in infrastructure charging, yet ultimately<br />

downplays the central argument made by environmental advocates that the internalization<br />

of external (environmental) costs should be recognized as a policy goal in itself, and not<br />

simply as a matter of pricing efficiency and a readjustment of market distortions (for a<br />

more extensive elaboration of this point, see T&E 1999).<br />

5.3.7 Transport-specific Conclusions of the Gothenburg European Council<br />

As noted above, transport was listed as one of the four priority areas singled out<br />

by the EU’s Göteborg Council in June 2001 to target environmental priorities for<br />

sustainability. More specifically, the presidency conclusions provide the following<br />

important definition of EU sustainable transport policy (European Union 2001:6-7):<br />

A sustainable transport policy should tackle rising volumes of traffic and levels of<br />

congestion, noise and pollution and encourage the use of environment-friendly modes<br />

of transport as well as full internalisation of social and environmental costs. Action is<br />

needed to bring about a significant decoupling of transport growth and GDP growth,<br />

in particular by a shift from road to rail, water, and public passenger transport. To<br />

achieve this the European Council:<br />

- invites the European Parliament and the Council to adopt by 2003 revised guidelines<br />

for trans-European transport networks on the basis of a forthcoming Commission<br />

proposal, with a view to giving priority, where appropriate, to infrastructure<br />

investment for public transport and for railways, inland waterways, short sea<br />

shipping, intermodal operations and effective interconnections;


204<br />

- notes that the Commission will propose a framework to ensure that by 2004 the price<br />

of using different modes of transport better reflects costs to society.<br />

[Emphasis added].<br />

This statement represents an unequivocal commitment on the part of the European<br />

Union to move away from a purely market-demand driven transport action framework<br />

that simply assesses future transport infrastructure needs on the basis on current mode<br />

shares and GDP growth forecasts. If it were to be translated into concrete policy action,<br />

this commitment would in fact bring about extensive adjustments to EU transport-sector<br />

decision-making and financing, essentially replacing current growth-accommodating<br />

strategies of transport infrastructure provision with an entirely new, goal-oriented<br />

approach that specifically targeted investments into particular modes over others.<br />

However, key Commission documents issued in the wake of the Gothenburg summit<br />

quickly retracted from this ambitious commitment.<br />

5.3.8 The White Paper “EU Transport Policy for 2010: Time to Decide”<br />

Published in September 2001, this document represents the Commissions latest<br />

and most comprehensive statement on transport policy, with sustainable mobility still<br />

featuring as the stated central aim. The paper has not been well-received by interest<br />

groups, however. The paper is comparatively long (over 100 pages excluding annexes)<br />

and organized according to various transport issues and modes, with a heavy overall<br />

focus on congestion as a central problem. The term “sustainable” is used extensively<br />

throughout the entire document, but again, no truly new or innovative concepts are<br />

introduced. Most importantly, the EU’s call for a decoupling of transport growth from<br />

economic growth voiced in the Gothenburg Summit is watered down or even ignored.


205<br />

For example, the new White Paper is explicitly calling for extensive new airport<br />

infrastructures to “cope with growth.” Overall, the gist of the paper stands in significant<br />

contrast to the EU’s new Sustainable Development Strategy (SDS) presented only a few<br />

months earlier. Where one would expect the Commission to focus on the problem of<br />

rising volumes of traffic, one finds calls for the additional funding of infrastructure<br />

instead. This is moderated by multiple calls for shifting between modes, but modal shifts<br />

in an of themselves of course do not decrease traffic. The pro-investment approach is<br />

flanked by a strong focus on “bottlenecks”, i.e. a rhetoric which rather limits policy<br />

discussions to the subject of congestion relief, and inappropriately skews vision away<br />

from environmental problems arising from rising transport volumes (also see Chapter 6).<br />

NGOs are particularly critical of not only the content but also the process by<br />

which this paper was produced. They see an increasing trend towards less openness and<br />

greater secrecy under the new Commissioner for Transport and Energy, Loyola de<br />

Palacio. In fact, the only consultation of interested parties with regard to the White Paper<br />

took place under the previous Commission prior to the merging of the transport and<br />

energy directorates, when Neil Kinnock was the responsible transport commissioner.<br />

The paper was extensively redrafted internally, resulting in numerous delays.<br />

Significantly, as the European Federation for Transport and Environment (T&E) reports<br />

in an October 18, 2001 news release, “the White Paper when adopted was immediately<br />

viewed as inadequate by the Joint Informal Council of Transport and Environment<br />

Ministers, falling short as it does of the political demands of EU leaders made at


206<br />

Gothenburg in June 2001.” 12<br />

For additional information on the 2001 White Paper,<br />

particularly its emphasis on bottlenecks, see Chapter 6.<br />

5.3.9 The DG TREN Website<br />

The gist of the statements on the current DG Transport and Energy Website<br />

stands in sharp contrast to the many much more wide-ranging definitions of sustainable<br />

transport. DG TREN has recently extensively revamped its website, providing short<br />

sound bites of information on every major transport topic. Couched in over-simplistic<br />

language, the current administration is thus presenting a capsule outline of EU transport<br />

policy to the interested public. In stark contrast to above presented comprehensive<br />

definitions, but concurrent with the 1993 White Paper on Growth, transport is frequently<br />

referred to as the “life-blood of our economy” implying that to stymie transport is to<br />

stymie growth. Under the sub-heading “Rethinking transport: ‘sustainable mobility’” DG<br />

TREN outlines its vision for a move towards “sustainable mobility,” presented partially<br />

in a question-and-answer format. The main problem according to this introduction is not<br />

the environmental impact of transport but congestion. The following paragraph seems<br />

indicative of DG TREN’s current growth-oriented stance:<br />

In a word, our transport systems are in danger of grinding to a halt. Increasingly they<br />

are synonymous with pollution and danger. And if transport seizes up, the whole of<br />

the economy will pay the price. So what can be done? Can the volume of transport be<br />

reduced? No – the demand for mobility is ever-increasing, and any prohibitive<br />

measures would seriously hamper the working of our society.<br />

[CEC, DG TREN 2001]<br />

12 As a partial response to DG TRENs lack of openness and consultation, transport- and energy-oriented<br />

European environmental groups decided to boycott the Commission’s First Annual Conference on Energy<br />

and Transport in Barcelona in October 2001.


207<br />

This online refusal to consider strategies to reduce the volume of transport is not<br />

only out of touch with much state-of-the-art thinking on sustainable transport as<br />

presented in this chapter, it also flies in the face of the EU’s current pursued goal to<br />

decouple transport growth from economic growth in general, most publicly stated at the<br />

Gothenburg summit. The analogy presented here remains stuck in old thinking schemes<br />

that regard any reduction in transport volumes as an impediment to growth.<br />

5.3.10 Pan-European Declarations on Sustainable Transport<br />

Outside of official EU documents, EU Transport Ministers, as well as their CEE<br />

counterparts, made rhetorical commitments to sustainable transport in two key Pan-<br />

European documents. For one, the 1997 UN-ECE Regional Conference on Transport and<br />

the Environment resulted in the “Vienna Declaration on Transport and the Environment.”<br />

The document reaffirms both the Rio declaration and recent European initiatives (United<br />

Nations Economic Commission for Europe 1997). 13<br />

Secondly, the June 1999 WHO<br />

Conference Transport, Environment and Health resulted in an ambitious Charter signed<br />

by European health, environment and transport ministers, together with the relevant<br />

13 The declaration recalls the importance of the Sustainable Transportation Principles developed at the 1996<br />

OECD conference in Vancouver, urges remaining states to ratify the Convention on Long-Range<br />

Transboundary Air Pollution and the related protocols, and draws attention to increasing pollution from air<br />

and maritime transport. The declaration also encourages phasing-out leaded fuels and considers providing<br />

ECE member countries in transition with appropriate assistance in restructuring the vehicle and oil-refining<br />

industries. It refers to the ESPOO convention in encouraging more effective environmental impact<br />

assessment of transport infrastructure projects in transboundary contexts and calls for further development<br />

of SEA methodologies. It also promotes several more radical measures such as the establishment of<br />

national environmental and health targets in the transport sector within national strategies, dedicated cycle<br />

networks, and road pricing. Yet it also cautiously warns that “the different geographic and economic<br />

circumstances of [UN-ECE] member states may necessitate differentiated approaches and flexibility of<br />

choice within that framework [of sustainable development]” and therefore recognizes “the special<br />

circumstances and priority needs of ECE member countries in transition” [para (g) and (n)]. The annex to<br />

the declaration contained a detailed Programme of Joint Action (POJA) in the fields of transport and<br />

environment, listing possible measures and solutions at the international and national level. Also note that<br />

in July 2002, UN ECE, in collaboration with the WHO, launched the “Transport, Health and Environment<br />

Pan-European Programme (THE PEP).” Also see http://www.unece.org/poja/


208<br />

WHO representatives (World Health Organization 1999). The charter highlights the<br />

specific and wide-ranging impacts of transport activities and infrastructures on human<br />

health. The spirit and approach in the Charter aims at effectively integrating existing<br />

efforts into future action plans. 14<br />

5.4 EU Discourses on Sustainable Urban Development<br />

Sustainable development cannot be achieved without a major focus on cities. This<br />

is particularly true for Europe and North America, where already over three-fourths, or<br />

76 percent, of the population live in urbanized areas. This figure is expected to rise to<br />

83.5 percent by the year 2030 (UNFPT 2001). About one in five Europeans lives in a<br />

conurbation larger than a quarter million inhabitants (CEC 1997:4). In 2000, almost half<br />

of the world's population lived in cities, and by 2030 this percentage is expected to<br />

increase to over 60 percent (UNFPA 2001). 15<br />

Responding to this challenge, the EU has<br />

begun to more explicitly voice its own urban strategies in recent years. Of course, there<br />

is no single one working definition of urban sustainability within the EU. As<br />

everywhere, there is a great variety of definitions. Yet the following review of key EU<br />

statements on urban sustainability demonstrates how much transport and land-use issues<br />

14 A first annex provides up-to-date scientific evidence on key issues (e.g. the quantifiable positive effects<br />

of cycling and walking and the enormous social costs of motorized transport from accidents, noise and<br />

pollution). A second annex then provides a detailed overview of existing relevant international actions,<br />

differentiating between legally binding documents (e.g. the Convention on Transboundary Air Pollution)<br />

and non-binding efforts and declarations. Also see http://www.euro.who.int/transport<br />

15 Although 90 percent of this growth is likely to be in less developed countries, mature economies in<br />

industrialized countries likewise have to contend with the challenge of making their settlement structures<br />

more sustainable. However, the frequently presumed positive relationship between urban compactness and<br />

sustainability remains controversial even in the recent literature on the subject, especially when it comes to<br />

discussing the sustainability aspects of dense and crowded developing country cities in comparison to<br />

developed country cities with more dispersed settlement structures (see e.g. Jenks 2000, Burgess 2000).<br />

Richardson et al. (2000:32) correctly note that discussions on the application of sustainability in an urban<br />

context have been inconsistent and often been limited to non-automobile dependence and ecological<br />

footprint discussions.


209<br />

are seen as being intimately related and in need of being treated in more integrated ways,<br />

particularly in urban areas. Note that “urban sprawl” emerges as a central concern in<br />

these EU policy statements – something to keep in mind for our discussion of EUfunding<br />

for the Budapest ring road in Chapter 9 (which also defines the term concisely).<br />

5.4.1 The Communication “Towards an Urban Agenda in the EU”<br />

In 1997, partly in follow-up and reaction to the 1996 UN Habitat II Conference in<br />

Istanbul, the Commission presented a Communication entitled Towards an urban agenda<br />

in the European Union (CEC 1997a) that outlined the challenges facing European cities.<br />

It acknowledged Europe’s towns and cities as the primary sources of wealth creation but<br />

also focused on the problems facing urban areas. Interestingly, the terms sustainable or<br />

sustainability do not appear in any of the headlines or subsections of the report.<br />

However, the document emphasizes the strong relationship between urban and transport<br />

policy matters by ultimately highlighting<br />

the impact of some key actions in four policy areas which have a particular bearing on<br />

the growth and development of Europe’s cities:<br />

policies which promote economic competitiveness and employment<br />

policy in favor of economic and social cohesion<br />

policies which help the insertion of cities into transEuropean networks<br />

policies promoting sustainable development and the quality of life in cities”<br />

(CEC 1997:8)<br />

The fact that the relationship between urban developments and EU cohesion<br />

strategies is clearly acknowledged and dealt with extensively in the Annex is important,<br />

but we reserve our discussion on cohesion objectives to later chapters. What interests us<br />

here is the fact that the Commission, in its section Transport and transEuropean<br />

Networks, presents the TENs as crucial for urban development and urban policies. There


210<br />

is mention of the need to “alleviate the problems of peripheral areas by linking them to<br />

the core of the Community as well as linking these areas together through improved<br />

infrastructure.” However, the role of the TENs is entirely defined as an accessibility<br />

issue, without reference to sustainability questions:<br />

TransEuropean Transport Networks (TETNs) are also instrumental in terms of<br />

improving access to cities, generating employment and allowing exchanges between<br />

cities and regions. More generally the TENs have the potential to open up Community<br />

territory, generating new opportunities for cities connected to the network. … Cities<br />

themselves form the nodal point which conncets modal networks and are therefore<br />

essential elements of the TETNs.<br />

Of course, urban sustainability discussions are amply provided in other recent<br />

Commission documents, and, indirectly, even in other parts of this document, with<br />

transport elements usually concentrating on the need to ease urban traffic congestion,<br />

promote public transport and non-motorized means of travel, improve intermodality and<br />

better integrate land use planning and transport.<br />

5.4.2 Sustainable Urban Development in the EU: A Framework for Action<br />

Published on the heels of the 1997 Agenda, this Framework for Action<br />

(Commission of the European Communities 1998a) aimed at “a better coordinated and<br />

targeted community action for urban problems” and set out a Community rationale for an<br />

examination of EU policies from an urban perspective. Of its four strategic<br />

interdependent policy aims, one actually explicitly targets sustainability (“Protecting and<br />

improving the urban environment: towards local and global sustainability”). The<br />

framework was discussed at a large “Urban Forum” which the Commission organized in<br />

Vienna in November 1998. However, while pointing to the urban dimensions of several


211<br />

transport-related policies, the Commission ultimately resisted making any commitments<br />

in this particular arena but instead remained wary of the subsidarity principle.<br />

5.4.3 The European Spatial Development Perspective<br />

Both the European Spatial Development Perspective (ESDP) adopted in Potsdam<br />

in 1999 in its final version by all EU Ministers responsible for Spatial Planning and the<br />

related CEMAT guidelines, contain many principles and recommendations designed to<br />

develop more sustainable land use structures. In its section two, “Spatial Development<br />

Issues of European Significance,” the ESDP (EC 1999:64) contains a special sub-section<br />

on Continuing Urban Sprawl which warns that<br />

uncontrolled growth results in increased levels of private transport; increases energy<br />

consumption; makes infrastructure and services more costly; and has negative effects<br />

on the quality of the countryside and the environment.<br />

Finding it “necessary to work together to find sustainable solutions for planning<br />

and managing urban growth” the ESDP makes explicit reference to the Dutch “compact<br />

city approach,” “land recycling” in Germany and to “target group” approaches (EC<br />

1999:66). 16<br />

16 Despite this rhetoric, it is certainly possible -- although not appropriate for this particular study -- to<br />

make the argument that the ESDP's core policy aims have themselves very problematic implications with<br />

regard to land use in major agglomerations, since the ESDP philosophy is often partial to the deconcentration<br />

of core economic areas and an overall de-densification of European territory. More<br />

concretely, the ESDP section on “Policy aims and Options for the Territory of the EU” calls for the<br />

development of a “polycentric and balanced urban system,” for “overcoming the outdated dualism between<br />

city and countryside” and for “parity of access to infrastructure and knowledge” (EC 1999:19-20). Even<br />

without venturing deeply into incinerating debates over the nature of polycentricity and polynucleated<br />

regions in Europe (also see Chapter 6), it should be pointed out that this approach is not necessarily<br />

congruent with an active promotion of compact city approaches in major urban capitals.


212<br />

5.4.4 The EU’s Input Papers to the 9 th UN CSD Conference in 2001<br />

Official EU inputs to the 2001 United Nations Commission on Sustainable<br />

Development Conference on Transport and Energy mention urban sprawl as a key trend<br />

and reason for concern, finding that it has encouraged longer trips, pushed people further<br />

out of urban centers and discouraged people from walking and cycling (EU 2001:4).<br />

Another short Issues Paper by the EU (EU 2000) for the CSD session of the previous year<br />

“sets out some of the main points and recommendation for action” of the EU on the<br />

sectoral theme of Integrated planning and the management of land resources. Here, we<br />

find the EU urging that “land use and urban planning should be better integrated with<br />

transport planning in order to achieve spatial structures which will reduce the need for<br />

travel and traffic.” The EU also wants to:<br />

encourage governments to adopt integrated policies in order to minimise unplanned<br />

urban sprawl and avoid the [sic] urban congestion.<br />

encourage governments to co-operate in order to share knowledge, to implement best<br />

practices and to develop common strategies at different levels<br />

emphasise the responsibility of all sectors for sustainable land use management as<br />

well as the importance of co-ordination of cross sectoral co-operation in land use<br />

planning, including effective stakeholder participation and public/private partnerships.<br />

[Emphasis added.]<br />

These are ambitious EU recommendations which we should keep in mind when<br />

analyzing EU funding for transport infrastructures in CEE (see esp. Chapter 9).


213<br />

5.5 The EU’s Research Frameworks: Funding for the Eco-modernist Agenda<br />

In the previous chapter, I identified the European Science Foundation’s NECTAR<br />

transport research network as a prime example for a group of transport experts united by<br />

a moderate ecological modernization perspective that is currently the dominant approach<br />

to transport policy and planning in Europe. It is important to understand, however, that<br />

research networks of course do form themselves out of a void. Within Europe, it is<br />

increasingly the European Union itself which shapes the member state’s transport<br />

research agendas through its various Research Programs (RTD Framework Programs).<br />

These programs are worth as much as 13 billion Euros in research monies over a fouryear<br />

time span. Interestingly, the thematic makeup of these research agendas quite<br />

clearly demonstrates the EU’s overall discursive framework of ecological modernization.<br />

Table 5.2. provides an overview of the thematic limitations under which (sustainable)<br />

transport and mobility research is supported under the current EU Framework Program.<br />

As we can see, the EU’s research agenda has been both firmly set within the key terms of<br />

growth and competitiveness and undoubtedly friendly to government-funded, yet<br />

industry-led science.<br />

At the end of 2002, the EU will then present the Sixth Framework Program 2002-<br />

2006. The EU plans a complete overhaul of the overall structure such that one will not be<br />

able to extrapolate from the Fifth Framework to the Sixth Framework program (see<br />

CORDIS News 4-2002). Although extensively reshuffled and rearranged, the currently<br />

emerging thematic priorities remain dominated by an ecological modernization approach.<br />

For example, under the general heading “sustainable development, global change and<br />

ecosystems,” for example, we find what amounts to textbook lists of ecological


214<br />

modernization policies. First, the EU defines its priorities for “sustainable energy<br />

systems” which are in turn to be divided research into short-term impact research into<br />

“clean energy,” “energy savings and every efficiency,” and “alternative motor fuels,” and<br />

medium- to long-term impact research into “fuel cells,” “new technologies for energy<br />

carriers/transport and storage, in particular hydrogen,” “renewable energy technologies,”<br />

and “cleaner fossil fuel plants.” Secondly, EU research for “sustainable surface<br />

transport” is currently introduced in the following manner: 17<br />

The White Paper “European transport policy for 2010: time to decide” forecasts a<br />

transport demand growth by 2010 in the European Union of 38% for freight and 24%<br />

for passenger transport (base-year 1998). The already congested transport networks<br />

will have to absorb the additional traffic, and the trend suggests that the proportion<br />

absorbed by the less sustainable modes is likely to grow. The objective is<br />

consequently to both fight against congestion and to decelerate or even reverse these<br />

trends regarding the modal split … while supporting European industry’s<br />

competitiveness in the production and operation of transport means and systems.<br />

In other words, increasing mobility and related impacts are to be accepted as part<br />

of competitive growth, and the main aim of transport research and policy is to de-congest<br />

and shift traffic to lower impact, lower emission modes. The ensuing research priorities<br />

are thus not designed to actively restrain transport growth in Europe, but instead focus on<br />

“developing environmentally friendly transport systems and means of transport,” and on<br />

“making surface transport safer, more effective and more competitive.” In sum,<br />

sustainability once again appears as subservient to growth.<br />

17 All quotes taken from the 180-page “Amended proposals for Council Decisions concerning the specific<br />

programmes implementing the Sixth Framework Programme of the European Communicty for research,<br />

technological development and demonstration activities,” (Commission of the European Communities<br />

2002e).


215<br />

Table 5.2<br />

Transport-relevant Research funded under the EU Fifth Framework Program 18<br />

Research<br />

Theme<br />

Objectives Sub-Themes Relevant for Research on<br />

Transport & Mobility<br />

To realize the benefits of “New methods of work and electronic<br />

IST the information society for commerce”<br />

Creating a<br />

user-friendly<br />

information<br />

society<br />

Europe both by<br />

accelerating its emergence<br />

and by ensuring that the<br />

needs of individuals and<br />

enterprises are met.<br />

“Essential technologies and infrastructures “<br />

“Future and Emerging Technologies”<br />

GROWTH<br />

Promoting<br />

competitive<br />

and<br />

sustainable<br />

growth<br />

ESSD<br />

Energy,<br />

environment<br />

and<br />

sustainable<br />

development<br />

To support research<br />

activities contributing to<br />

competitiveness and<br />

sustainability, particularly<br />

where these two objectives<br />

interact.<br />

Industry's role will not<br />

only be to identify areas<br />

for collaboration but also<br />

to bring together and<br />

integrate projects,<br />

especially cross-sectoral<br />

projects along the value<br />

chain, so that technology<br />

uptake and innovation are<br />

more effectively ensured<br />

across Europe.<br />

To contribute to<br />

sustainable development<br />

by focusing on key<br />

activities crucial for social<br />

well-being<br />

and economic<br />

competitiveness in<br />

Europe.<br />

“Sustainable mobility & intermodality:<br />

(a) a regulatory & accountable framework<br />

reflecting socio-economic objectives;<br />

(b) an interoperable infrastructure which allows<br />

the operation of attractive, environmentally<br />

friendly and efficient transport means;<br />

(c) modal and intermodal systems for managing<br />

operations and providing services”<br />

“Land transport & marine technologies:<br />

(a) the development of critical technologies and<br />

(b) their integration and validation around<br />

advanced industrial concepts in order to attain<br />

the following main deliverables:<br />

(i) improved fuel efficiency and reduction of<br />

emissions ;<br />

(ii) improved performance and<br />

(iii) improved system competitiveness”<br />

“Global change, climate and biodiversity“<br />

“The city of tomorrow and cultural heritage,<br />

concentrating on:<br />

(a) city planning and management,<br />

(b) cultural heritage,<br />

(c) built environment,<br />

(d) urban transport”<br />

“Study of socio-economic aspects of<br />

development of environmental change”<br />

Source: Selected and compiled from http://www.cordis.lu/fp5/home.html<br />

18<br />

The EU’s Fifth Framework Program runs from 1998 to 2002 and consists of four general research themes<br />

(“Thematic Programs”) worth about € 10.85 billion and three horizontal programs worth about € 2.12<br />

billion. The horizontal programs were omitted from the above table. Also, since the fourth theme,<br />

“Quality of Life and management of living resources,” worth about € 2.41 billion did not include any<br />

directly transport-relevant research agendas, it was also dropped from the overview table.


216<br />

5.6 Conclusions and Open Questions<br />

EU documents referring to sustainable development and sustainable transport exhibit<br />

a clear tendency to adhere to the underlying rationales of ecological modernization, i.e.<br />

they express confidence that economic growth, environmental protection and social<br />

equity are somehow complementary goals. When forced to set general priorities, EU<br />

policy-makers emphasize growth before ecology and equity.<br />

However, we also have to conclude that, in the end, the EU is not always strictly<br />

adhering to the discursive framework of ecological modernization in its formulation of<br />

policy objectives. Instead, the EU borrows rather freely from a variety of rationales, be<br />

this the result of intentional strategizing or unintentional multifaceted rationalizing on the<br />

part of EU decision-makers. So in the end, EU policy statements on sustainable transport<br />

remain inconsistent. Statements coming out of the DG Environment are often more<br />

environmentally ambitious than formulations coming from DG Transport and Energy.<br />

Some formulations are openly contradictory, and the exact nature of these internal<br />

contradictions needs to be more closely investigated in ensuing chapters.<br />

Moreover, in the real world, actual transport infrastructure investment decisions bring<br />

forward not only theoretical but also practical controversies. Baeten (2000) made the<br />

important point that throughout Europe, many examples of large scale transport<br />

investments can be found that demonstrate the “deeply contested ways and means<br />

through which transport infrastructures are being planned and developed.” So at times,<br />

overly optimistic sustainability discourses even render a disservice to the opposing<br />

factions. Often, diametrically opposed mobility interests are at work which cannot, and


217<br />

perhaps should not, be united into a common sustainability definition. Baeten’s<br />

(2000:70) key insight is worth quoting at length here:<br />

The conflicting character of transport planning is remarkably absent in the sustainable<br />

transport discourse. The harmonious and conflict-avoiding vocabulary of the<br />

sustainability agenda is unable to cope with material processes that shape and<br />

transform infrastructure networks. Yet, sustainable development and sustainable<br />

transport are policy concepts which are currently widely accepted at international,<br />

national and local policy level. It has generated a new optimism among transport<br />

planners, since it seems to provide them with a fresh theoretical platform from which<br />

to launch new pragmatic planning measures, backed up be a brad, almost globally<br />

constructed consensus about the necessity of its implementation. At the same time,<br />

however, it is not difficult to observe the remarkable discrepancy between, on one<br />

hand, the legitimacy of sustainable transport concepts, and, on the other hand, the poor<br />

theoretical elaboration of these concepts.<br />

Whitelegg (1993:34) presents a very similar assessment. In particular, he points<br />

to the discrepancy between supposedly ‘sustainable’ EU policy initiatives and actual<br />

investment plans:<br />

Sustainability, if it is to amount to more than rhetoric, must be associated with clear<br />

goals and measures that have some potential to achieve these goals. This is not the<br />

case with the European Commission (EC) pronouncements on sustainability [as<br />

outlined in CEC 1992a]. The EC has invoked the rhetoric of sustainability at the same<br />

time as advocating the construction of 12500km of new motorway standard roads<br />

(costed at 130 billion ECUs) in Europe [CEC 1992b] and without any evaluation of<br />

alternative strategies to solve transport problems. The publication of road plans in<br />

advance of a major White Paper on transport policy [CEC 1992c] is further evidence<br />

of a clear disregard for environmental issues and the transformation of sustainability<br />

into an argument to support traditional policies.<br />

We thus return to our core theme of rhetoric versus reality. More importantly, we<br />

once again see opposing discursive frameworks at work. In turn, these discursive<br />

frameworks often seem to be linked with material interests and decision-making claims<br />

different stakeholders have with regard to particular types of transport investments. That<br />

is: policy formulations typically appear as rationalizations and reflections of real-life


218<br />

power relationships. This is also where the Flyvbjergian dimension of Realrationalität<br />

enters the picture. But if this is true, then Whitelegg’s accusation that the EU simply<br />

“disregards the environment” is too simple. In comparison to both road industry<br />

lobbyists and environmentalists, Commission officials would seem to have fewer<br />

personal, material interests at stake. Rationalizations must thus be shaped at a more<br />

abstract, conceptual level.<br />

So who and what really influences these EU decision-makers when it comes to<br />

the actual formulation of transport sector investment strategies? Is there really just an<br />

obvious discrepancy between stated sustainability goals and unsustainable deeds? This<br />

chapter has shown that the EU is in fact not binding itself to any radical interpretation of<br />

sustainable transport the same way that political economists or environmentalists do. So<br />

measured within its own discursive framework, the EU appears less hypocritical than<br />

seen from without. Whether we like it or not is a different matter – and arguing against<br />

this status quo belongs into the realm of normative theorizing and political activism.<br />

What interests me in the following chapters, however, is the complex, mutual relationship<br />

between the EU’s eco-modernist formulation of sustainable transport strategies on one<br />

hand, and actual investment plans and programs on the other hand. In order to carry out<br />

this type of analysis, I will take a more thematic discourse analytical approach.


219<br />

Printed on Thursday, October 31, 2002<br />

CHAPTER 6<br />

Three Leitbilder and Four Spatial Storylines for<br />

EU Transport Infrastructure Investments<br />

6.1 Introduction..................................................................................................... 220<br />

6.2 Three Overarching Leitbilder for EU Decision-Making ................................ 222<br />

6.2.1 Defining Leitbilder (Guiding Visions).................................................... 222<br />

6.2.2 Integration (Deepening).......................................................................... 225<br />

6.2.3 Enlargement (Widening)......................................................................... 227<br />

6.2.4 Sustainability........................................................................................... 228<br />

6.3 Four Spatial Storylines For EU Transport Infrastructure Investments ........... 231<br />

6.3.1 Defining “Spatial Storylines” ................................................................. 231<br />

6.3.2 The Context: The Trans-European Transport Networks (TENs) ........... 233<br />

6.3.3 Cohesion ................................................................................................. 236<br />

6.3.4 Polycentricity.......................................................................................... 247<br />

6.3.5 Missing Links.......................................................................................... 254<br />

6.3.6 Bottlenecks.............................................................................................. 262<br />

6.4 Conclusions: The Challenge of Prioritizing Investments ............................... 265


220<br />

6.1 Introduction<br />

So far, I traced the contradictions and biases in key EU documents seeking to<br />

define sustainable development, sustainable transport and sustainable mobility and<br />

thereby demonstrated the conflicted nature of the concept of sustainability. I also<br />

pinpointed the EU’s general, growth-oriented, eco-modernist approach to transport<br />

policy-making and set it in relation to other, alternative discursive frameworks. The<br />

previous chapter then provided a text-oriented discourse analysis of key EU policy<br />

statements on transport, sustainability and land use. This present chapter will continue<br />

this discourse-focused analysis by exploring how growth and efficiency-oriented<br />

arguments play out in the more specific arena of EU transport infrastructure investment<br />

policies and programs.<br />

Given the challenges of multi-level governance and multi-location politics, it is<br />

always quite difficult, if not to say impossible, for any one stakeholder or group to push<br />

through their particular decision-making agenda without first forging alliances with other<br />

groups. This present chapter will elaborate on the topic of the EU’s power-knowledgenexus<br />

by taking a thematic approach. Rather than concentrate on particular stakeholders,<br />

I will instead focus on particular visions and themes that have been formulated with<br />

regard to transport-sector infrastructure support at the European level. I identify three<br />

overarching visions, or Leitbilder, and four “spatial storylines” justifying EU transport<br />

infrastructure investments. The key insight, taken from Foucauldian discourse theory, is<br />

that the investment-related “storylines” most likely have not been formulated by any one<br />

identifiable author / stakeholder alone, but are instead to be understood as the result of


221<br />

longstanding, ongoing and mutually inspiring, yet often contradictory discourses related<br />

to the objectives of transport and land-use development in Europe.<br />

Over the course of the last few years, Tim Richardson and Ole. B. Jensen have<br />

published several articles applying a discourse theoretical approach to European Union<br />

policy in the areas of transport and spatial development (Richardson 1996; Richardson<br />

and Jensen 2000; Jensen and Richardson 2001). They employ Foucauldian discourse<br />

analysis and declare their intellectual affinity with Bent Flyvbjerg’s work on rationality<br />

(or rather: Realrationalität) and power in planning. This present chapter is in many ways<br />

complementary to their ongoing research, although it is overall somewhat less explicitly<br />

Foucauldian than their work. The other obvious influence is Maarten Hajer’s work on<br />

environmental discourse and storylines (also see below). The central proposition of this<br />

chapter is what I term the “Conflicting-Storylines” proposition. It assumes that<br />

1) EU decision-making for Pan-European transport investments lacks consistence<br />

and sustainability due to the existence of several, partially complementary, but<br />

also partially competing EU development objectives, and<br />

2) these objectives are in turn expressed through several, partially conflicting<br />

Leitbilder and spatial storylines. 1<br />

So this chapter focuses on identifying the specific discursive practices by means<br />

of which the European Union advances its underlying eco-modernist transport investment<br />

rationales. Note that this chapter is deliberately limited in scope in the sense that there is<br />

an explicit focus on infrastructure investments, thus excluding discourses that are more<br />

1 A Leitbild (guiding vision) can be very broadly understood as an overarching storyline. For more precise<br />

definitions, see below.


222<br />

focused on regulatory or managerial aspects of European transport policy. 2 Interestingly,<br />

the identified storylines do not only exemplify eco-modernist rationales, but sometimes<br />

also evoke various other discursive frameworks.<br />

The rest of the chapter is organized as follows: In the section following this<br />

introduction, I introduce the German concept Leitbild in order to differentiate the EU’s<br />

overarching (history-making) “guiding visions” of enlargement, integration and<br />

sustainability, from second-order (policy-setting and –shaping) concepts (i.e. storylines)<br />

such as “polycentricity” or “bottlenecks”. 3<br />

I briefly discuss the three above-named<br />

Leitbilder for EU decision-making before moving on to the core concept of “spatial<br />

storylines.” I subsequently analyze what I identify as four main spatial storylines for EU<br />

infrastructure decision-making: “cohesion,” “polycentricity,” “missing links,” and<br />

“bottlenecks.” I also discuss their relationship to the EU’s eco-modernist understanding<br />

of sustainable development. A concluding section summarizes the theoretical findings<br />

and their implications for decision-making.<br />

6.2 Three Overarching Leitbilder for EU Decision-Making<br />

6.2.1 Defining Leitbilder (Guiding Visions)<br />

There is no direct translation for the German term Leitbild (pronounced lite-bild).<br />

As a compound noun, its most literal English translation is “guiding image.” I use the<br />

general term Leitbild here in the same sense that Meinolf Dierkes and his colleagues at<br />

2 It would be quite possible, for example, to do detailed discourse-theoretical analyses of eco-modernist<br />

storylines such as “Intelligent Transport”, “Interoperability” or “Fair Payment for Infrastructure Use” or<br />

“Safety”. These are beyond the scope of my project, but certainly present worthwhile areas for further<br />

research.<br />

3 This now commonly referred to three-level typology of EU decision-making (i.e. history-making / policysetting<br />

/ policy-shaping) was introduced by Peterson and Bomberg (1999, see especially Chapter 1, p. 12).<br />

They do not, however, develop a typology of pertaining discursive concepts the way I do here.


223<br />

the Social Science Research Center <strong>Berlin</strong> (Wissenschaftszentrum für Sozialforschung<br />

<strong>Berlin</strong> - WZB) utilize it, namely to connote a trend-setting and action-guiding notion<br />

about a viable and desirable future that acts as a common orienting, motivating and<br />

coordinating frame of reference for representatives from different cultures of knowledge<br />

(Dierkes, Hoffmann et al. 1992; Hoffmann and Marz 1992; Dierkes and Marz 1998;<br />

Hoffmann and Marz 2000). In the German-language literature, Leitbilder are normally<br />

regarded as serving rather specific functions. In planning, Leitbilder are central<br />

categories demarking the goal-oriented governance of planning schemes. Initially, these<br />

(spatial) Leitbilder are often coined without particular actions in mind; but due to their<br />

imagery and linguistic content they typically end up providing implicit and intuitive<br />

guidance throughout the planning and implementation process, be it with regard to the<br />

overall conceptualization, or with regard to the planning, the operationalization, the<br />

implementation or even the evaluation of a decision-making process. In short, Leitbilder<br />

connote a particular vision for a desirable urban or regional future.<br />

To briefly illustrate the point: German discussions on urban, regional and spatial<br />

planning have been dominated by three main urban Leitbilder in the last 50 years, all of<br />

which are also applicable to the wider European context: 1) the car-oriented<br />

(“autogerechte”) City, 2) the Compact City, and the 2) Network City or Zwischenstadt.<br />

Beginning in the 1970s and 1980s, the modernist Leitbild of the car-oriented city, which<br />

was to be functionally separated and dispersed (“gegliedert und aufgelockert”),<br />

prompted a backlash call for the Compact European City. While this alternative vision of<br />

a walkable, transit-oriented city with a dense urban core is still held in high esteem by<br />

most planners (including many New Urbanists, who have simultaneously reified and


224<br />

perverted it), urban theorists increasingly argue that the Leitbild of the Compact<br />

European City is inevitably a conservative, backward-looking notion that no longer<br />

conforms to the spatial reality of today’s German cities (Siebel 2000). Nevertheless, it<br />

serves to uphold the ideal of a multi-functional, mixed-use urban environment that is not<br />

dominated by private cars. By contrast, Sieverts (1998) proclaimed the rise of the<br />

Zwischenstadt (literally: In-Between City) or Network City which rejects notions of<br />

hierarchy and centrality in favor of a vision of an expansive, urbanized landscape that is<br />

functionally interconnected and interdependent. Critics, however, see in it no more than<br />

a legitimation of sprawling tendencies and unfettered suburbanization (cf. Kühn<br />

2000:22).<br />

To conclude, Leitbilder are formed through the interaction of stakeholders. In<br />

turn, a Leitbild functions to structure and organize action and decision-making, so that the<br />

relationship between a Leitbild and the persons and institutions applying it is<br />

interdependent and mutually reinforcing. It should also be noted that while they are<br />

generally intended to be guiding rather than prescriptive, Leitbilder, such as the Network<br />

City, are sometimes overextended and simultaneously applied on the analytical,<br />

normative and prognostic levels. 4<br />

As far as the difference between Leitbilder and spatial storylines is concerned, the<br />

relationship between the two concepts can be summarized as follows: I limit the<br />

application of the term Leitbilder to the discussion of overarching, sector-independent<br />

4 Unfortunately, similar to their English language counterparts, many Germans scholars use the terms<br />

Leitbilder and Paradigmen (paradigms) almost interchangeably, especially with regard to spatial concepts.<br />

Please revert to section 3.4.1 in Chapter 3 for a full explanation of why I object to such a “lose” application<br />

of the term “paradigm” and why I therefore consciously seek to avoid its (over)use. To me, the term<br />

Leitbilder much more appropriately connotes the idea of broad, co-existing, partially competing frames of<br />

reference for decision-making.


225<br />

contradictions of EU decision-making objectives. By contrast, I use the term “spatial<br />

storylines” to I discuss notions that are second-order concepts which more specifically<br />

impact transport infrastructure decision-making and investments.<br />

Generally speaking, EU decision-making is always torn between the twin forces<br />

of enlargement and integration, i.e. decisions aiming at extending the borders of the<br />

current union on one hand, and decisions that foster a deepening of the Union and the<br />

completion of the Single Market on the other hand. EU transport policy is also torn<br />

between these objectives. More recently, there has been the addition of (environmental)<br />

sustainability Leitbild, which competes with development objectives related to<br />

enlargement and integration.<br />

6.2.2 Integration (Deepening)<br />

Manuel Castells (1998:338) observed that “European integration is, at the same<br />

time, a reaction to the process of globalization and its most advanced expression.” The<br />

Treaty on European Union (TEU) marked “a new stage in the process of creating an ever<br />

closer union among the peoples of Europe” (Article 1, TEU). 5<br />

This ever closer union is<br />

envisioned as a progressive force that has been present since the earliest beginnings of<br />

European unification. As the EU Glossary on Institutions, Policies and Enlargement of<br />

the European Union 6 notes:<br />

Deepening refers to the integration dynamic present from the outset of the European<br />

venture. Through the customs union, the common market, and then the Euro zone, the<br />

5 Unless otherwise noted, quotes from the TEU are taken from the consolidated version that includes<br />

provisions included in the Treaty of Amsterdam. See http://europa.eu.int/eur-lex/en/treaties/index.html for<br />

an overview and changes in organizational structure and content in the Treaty of Amsterdam compared to<br />

the Maastricht version.<br />

6 The Glossary is available online: http://europa.eu.int/scadplus/leg/en/cig/g4000i.htm (last accessed on<br />

September 3, 2002).


226<br />

European Communities have grown into what aspires to be an “ever closer union”<br />

among the peoples of Europe (Article 1 of the EU Treaty). Deepening is a process<br />

parallel to, and often viewed as a necessary step prior to, enlargement.<br />

With regard to the aim of integrating Europe and working towards a single<br />

market, the Common Transport Policy (CTP) was regarded by the Community’s initiators<br />

as an essential pillar for the achievement of the internal market and the free flow of<br />

goods, services, labor and capital across national borders.<br />

Until the signing of the Maastricht Treaty, emphasis lay on non-spatial, regulatory<br />

issues concerning the harmonization and taxation of transport services. It was only after<br />

the Maastricht commitment to develop Trans-European Networks that the spatial<br />

dimensions of European integration were directly addressed by the Community through<br />

infrastructure funding. 7<br />

Integration then also came to be understood not only as a spatial,<br />

but also as a modal objective. In his foreword to Turró’s TEN study, ex-Transport<br />

Commissioner Neil Kinnock explicitly appreciates “the emphasis he gives to integration<br />

– within modes, between modes, and across borders – as the leitmotiv of TENs<br />

development” (Turro 1999:foreword).<br />

In the end, however, European integration remains a complicated vision that<br />

attempts to unify economic, political and social forces that often seem irreconcilable.<br />

And, as Graham and Hart (1998:259) remind us, “European integration is largely a<br />

political process being orchestrated primarily through economic policies, which are often<br />

incompatible with the processes that defined the contested meanings of belonging in<br />

contemporary Europe.” The EU’s options of political intervention in the face of global<br />

competition and internal cultural diversity are thus clearly fraught with difficulties.


227<br />

6.2.3 Enlargement (Widening)<br />

The end of the Cold War, symbolized by the fall of the <strong>Berlin</strong> Wall, meant that<br />

the European Union had to radically rethink its prospects for further enlargement. The<br />

EU started to provide technical and financial assistance to the former Eastern Bloc<br />

countries almost immediately. The Europe Agreements, the first ones of which were<br />

signed with Poland and Hungary in late 1991, provided the basis for political, legal and<br />

trade-related issues as well as and other areas of cooperation, including environment and<br />

transport. Since then, Eastern enlargement has been a three track process, consisting of<br />

1) the pre-accession strategy focusing on reform in the ten candidate countries, 2) the<br />

preparation of Agenda 2000 and the opening of actual accession negotiations (with the<br />

first five in 1998, with the rest in 2000), and 3) the publication of the Communication<br />

Strategy for Enlargement in May 2000. The EU is well aware that further enlargement<br />

will mean adjustments to the current EU structure of governance:<br />

Enlargement was originally the term used to refer to the four successive waves of new<br />

members joining the Community. […] With the growing number of applicants for<br />

membership … , the concept of enlargement has taken on a very special significance.<br />

[…] To ensure that enlargement does not hinder European integration, any further<br />

accessions must be accompanied by reform of the institutions and of some Union<br />

policies.<br />

(Commission of the European Communities 1999a).<br />

The much lower infrastructure endowment of the candidate countries has led to<br />

the institution of the so-called pre-accession funds. Much of the focus in the transport<br />

sector is not only about expanding infrastructure, but also about harmonizing regulations<br />

and bringing existing networks up to EU standards. Overall, the rhetoric at both the<br />

7 Although the European Investment Bank (EIB) had of course already provided many millions of transport<br />

infrastructure loans aimed at promoting European integration.


228<br />

Commission and the Parliament is aimed at expanding European markets and improving<br />

interconnections throughout Europe, albeit always with a view to privileged high-speed<br />

routes:<br />

Within the framework of a system of open and competitive markets, action by the<br />

Community aims to establish and develop trans-European transport networks by<br />

promoting the interconnection and interoperability of national networks as well as<br />

access to such networks. In the area of transport the Community has identified<br />

transport routes whose expansion and coordination are intended to lead to a stronger<br />

network of links across the European continent. In this context, we should mention the<br />

construction of high-speed routes linking the metropolises of several Member States.<br />

As well as seeking to improve transport infrastructure, the trans-European networks<br />

are primarily intended to integrate Community transport systems by expanding and<br />

linking networks.<br />

(European Parliament 1999:4).<br />

Regardless of its difficulties, enlargement today is an EU Leitbild that has set in<br />

motion an irreversible process of accession for the Eastern European candidate states.<br />

The borders of the Union will likely keep moving eastward for some time to come.<br />

6.2.4 Sustainability<br />

Chapter 5 already traced the EU’s rhetorical commitment to sustainability, so<br />

there is no need to repeat the relevant EU documents here. The most important thing to<br />

remember is that it was only with the Treaty of Amsterdam that an explicit reference on<br />

sustainable development was written into the recitals of the EU Treaty. Chapter 5 also<br />

demonstrated that sustainability is not explicitly defined as a limiting factor on growth<br />

and productivity in the key documents that define the EU’s sustainability commitment.<br />

Some examples of such a more rigid interpretation can be found in other EU documents,<br />

however. The Second Report on Economic and Social Cohesion which the European<br />

Commission released in early 2001 contains a particularly interesting reminder that


229<br />

sustainability is necessarily both intergenerational as well as overarching concept. As the<br />

report notes in its “Conclusions and Recommendations” section in the beginning<br />

(Commission of the European Communities 2001e):<br />

Efforts to raise productivity and promote growth for one generation must not,<br />

however, be at the expense of the next. In other words, the development path followed<br />

must also be a sustainable one, a general point which needs to be reflected in all<br />

investment decisions.<br />

[Emphasis in the original.]<br />

Optimistically speaking, one might discern here the first mainstreaming effects of<br />

the EU’s new Sustainable Development Strategy, at least as far as rhetorical commitment<br />

is concerned. In the end, however, sustainability is indisputably only the most recent<br />

addition to the EU canon of Leitbilder. Both enlargement and integration are to be<br />

achieved in a “sustainable” manner, but this mandate remains operationally weak. For<br />

example, so far, the Maastricht sustainability mandate has not succeeded in bringing<br />

about the demanded shift towards funding for more environmentally friendly modes of<br />

transport. It is true, for example, that 9 out of the EU’s 14 TEN priority projects<br />

(described below) were high-speed rail projects and that over 60% (827 out of 1344<br />

million ECU) from the TEN special budget line went towards rail. But as figure 6.1<br />

indicates, the vast majority of transport spending under the more sizeable EU Cohesion<br />

and EDRF Funds went towards roads, tipping the overall balance about two-thirds in<br />

favor of roads and highways.


230<br />

Figure 6.1 Transport Grants within the EU-15 by Mode<br />

ERDF 94-99, TEN budget line 95-98,<br />

Cohesion Fund 93-97<br />

Airports &<br />

Ports<br />

8%<br />

Railways<br />

21%<br />

Other<br />

5%<br />

Total funds disbursed:<br />

21460 MECU<br />

Roads and<br />

highways<br />

66%<br />

Source: own compilation, using data from the European Commission<br />

Figure 6.2 Cohesion Fund Transport Grants by Country and Mode (1993-1997)<br />

Million Ecu<br />

3500<br />

3000<br />

2500<br />

2000<br />

1500<br />

1000<br />

500<br />

0<br />

Other<br />

Airports & Ports<br />

Rail<br />

Road<br />

SPAIN POR<strong>TU</strong>GAL GREECE IRELAND<br />

Source: Own compilation, using data from the European Commission<br />

Also, the rail funds were all dedicated to high-speed projects that also have large<br />

environmental impacts. From 1994-1999, over 2/3 of all available EDRF Objective 1<br />

funding went to roads. 8<br />

The imbalance was equally pronounced in the case of the<br />

Cohesion Fund. From 1993 to 1999, TEN-related priority transport investments to the


231<br />

four poorest member states (Greece, Ireland, Portugal and Spain) accounted for over 5<br />

billion Ecu, of which 69% went to roads (see figure 6.2).<br />

Enlargement in and of itself is increasingly used as a general justification for EU<br />

financing for Pan-European infrastructure investments, but this general argument lacks<br />

specificity. In order to gain a fuller understanding of the various rationales and<br />

rationalizations for EU involvement in transport infrastructure financing in the context of<br />

Eastern enlargement, it is therefore necessary to first trace in some detail the various,<br />

contradictory spatial storylines that have been advanced to justify EU involvement in<br />

transport infrastructure projects in the past.<br />

6.3 Four Spatial Storylines For EU Transport Infrastructure Investments<br />

6.3.1 Defining “Spatial Storylines”<br />

The principal conceptual innovation of Maarten Hajer’s book The Politics of<br />

Environmental Discourse consists in its focus on what he calls “storylines.” Hajer arrives<br />

at this emphasis after a careful and critical review of Foucault’s theory of discourse,<br />

which he finds wanting in one central aspect: “the role of the discoursing subject remains<br />

ambivalent” (p.51). Well-aware that in the Foucaultian post-positivist worldview,<br />

“discourse is not to be seen as a medium through which individuals can manipulate the<br />

world,” but that it “is itself part of reality, and constitutes the discoursing subject,” and<br />

that consequently, in this framework “interests cannot be taken as given a priori but are<br />

constituted through discourse,” Hajer ultimately finds that “there is still a conceptual gap<br />

between Foucault’s abstract work and the study of concrete political events,” which to<br />

8 Objective 1 funding is designated for the least developed regions of the EU, i.e. regions where GDP per<br />

capita is below 75% of the EU average.


232<br />

him points to “a need to devise middle range concepts through which [the] interaction<br />

between discourses can be related to the role of individual strategic action in a nonreductionist<br />

way” (pp.51-52). Hence his focus on discourse coalitions and storylines.<br />

These concepts are partly about bringing a certain amount of agency back into the<br />

picture. Rules and practices are only imbued with meaning as long as they are exercised<br />

by a particular person, and there is always choice involved in picking between different<br />

routines and in precise way in which these are exercised. In other words, rather than<br />

simply note the existence of certain linguistic practices or conventions through rhetorical<br />

analysis, what should interest us when looking at political and bureaucratic decisionmaking,<br />

is the use, re-use, and transformation of particular images, phrases or storylines,<br />

and who benefits from them.<br />

Originally an idea taken from Davies and Harré (1990), Hajer (1995:56) redefines<br />

a storyline as follows:<br />

A storyline, as I interpret it, is a generative sort of narrative that allows actors to draw<br />

upon various discursive categories to give meaning to specific physical or social<br />

phenomena. The key function of storylines is that they suggest a unity in the<br />

bewildering variety of separate discursive components parts of a problem.<br />

Hajer also immediately adds the following key statement:<br />

Political change may therefore well take place through the emergence of new<br />

storylines that re-order understandings. Finding the appropriate storyline becomes an<br />

important form of agency.<br />

Interestingly, although somewhat reluctantly admitting the term “agency” into his<br />

discourse vocabulary, Hajer seems ready at several points in his study to admit a<br />

necessary focus on what one might call the makers of a storyline. Other than in the world<br />

of creative writing, however, Hajer does not attach any importance to being the original


233<br />

creator of an idea or storyline. Rather, the key to discursive success in the world of<br />

communicative competition is the successful constitution of consensual meaning through<br />

adapting and re-defining a universally appealing storyline. 9<br />

Storylines cluster<br />

knowledge, position stakeholders and, ultimately, create coalitions. In identifying four<br />

major spatial storylines which have provided justifications for EU infrastructure<br />

assistance in the transport sector, I adapt Hajer’s concept of storylines to the particular<br />

case of transport infrastructure decisions in the European Union.<br />

6.3.2 The Context: The Trans-European Transport Networks (TENs)<br />

The idea of developing a coherent map of Trans-European Transport<br />

Infrastructure pre-dates the European Union and was already actively discussed in several<br />

other international forums, especially within the UN Economic Commission for Europe<br />

and within the OECD/European Conference of Ministers of Transport (ECMT). The<br />

concept of the so-called international E-routes was developed in the 1980s, but this was<br />

9 Note that Hajer especially turns his attention away from agency when he defines his second key element<br />

to his “argumentative approach” (a phrase borrowed from Forester and Fischer, 1993): discoursecoalitions.<br />

The concept is somewhat ambiguous (p.65):<br />

Discourse coalitions are defined as the ensemble of (1) a set of storylines; (2) the actors who utter these<br />

storylines; and (3) the practices in which this discursive activity is based. … Discourse coalitions are<br />

formed if previously independent practices are being actively related to one another, if a common<br />

discourse is created in which several practices get a meaning in a common political project.<br />

According to this definition, discourse coalitions are an amalgam of language, of people and of the rules<br />

governing people’s behavior at the same time. Note the use of the passive voice in the second part of<br />

Hajer’s definition, indicating that in contrast to typical uses of the term coalition, referring to groups of<br />

actors, the emphasis in Hajer’s definition is not on the people who make up the coalition, but rather on the<br />

storylines that are “seen as the discursive cement that keeps a discourse-coalition together” (p.65). Hence<br />

“storylines, not interests, form the basis of the coalition” (p.66). Nevertheless, Hajer subsequently<br />

recommends “searching for politics in new locations, looking for the activity of the actors who produce<br />

storylines” (p.66). He proceeds to use ecological modernization as an example to illustrate the concept of<br />

discourse coalitions. Yet in the end, the relationship between the developed discourse and the discoursing<br />

subjects remains unclear in Hajer’s definition of discourse coalitions. Most importantly, the role of the<br />

creators of a storyline are left ambiguous inasmuch as it is uncertain whether the creators of a particular<br />

storyline consciously develop this story line for use in a particular political (or social) context, or simply<br />

happen to come up with it “by chance.” As we will see in our example of different discourses surrounding<br />

EU transport infrastructure decision-making, both is possible.


234<br />

not connected to any idea of common funding schemes. The Trans-European Networks<br />

(TENs) of the European Commission, however, were always intended to be at least partly<br />

financed by the European Community/Union. The idea of coordinating and financing a<br />

series of priority infrastructure links first emerged in the early 1990s. The development<br />

of the TENs was always closely linked to the creation of the European Single market. In<br />

their most ambitious form, the complete TENs master plans foresaw public and private<br />

investments in the amount of 220 billion ECU until the year 2000 alone, of which the EU<br />

itself was prepared to supply about one tenth in grant funding. 10<br />

TEN infrastructure investments can be categorized into two main categories:<br />

network investments in underprivileged regions disbursed through the regular structural<br />

funds, and priority investments funded though the TEN budget line. Additionally, the<br />

European Investment Bank has provided funding for both types of investments.<br />

The TENs were not only the first spatial concept in European policies (Buunk<br />

1999:) but also the EU’s first large scale infrastructure policy. Although the TENs are<br />

frequently dismissed as simply expressing Member state preferences for national network<br />

connections that were yet to be completed, Piodi (1997:24) presents an important<br />

alternative interpretation:<br />

10 The development of the Trans-European transport networks has been assessed in much detail in the<br />

literature. In particular, there are four book-length manuscripts exclusively dedicated to the TENs, so it<br />

cannot be the place of the present study to reassess the entire process here. For a (now already outdated)<br />

account examining key TEN themes for the not only the transport, but also the energy and<br />

telecommunications sectors, see Debra Johnson’s and Colin Turner’s (1997) Trans-European Networks.<br />

For a policy-oriented account that (too) neatly divides the discussion over trans-European transport<br />

infrastructures into different sectors, see John Ross’ (1998) Linking Europe. For an engaged, prointegrationist<br />

and pro-multi-modal plea for the future development of the TENs, see Mateu Turró’s (1999)<br />

Going Trans-European. Finally, Tim Richardson’s Ph.D. thesis (2000) presents the kind of critical,<br />

discourse-analytical and planning theory-inspired assessment on the TEN process which is closest to my<br />

own study. Even his thesis, however, only marginally touches on the development of the Pan-European<br />

(Helsinki) Corridors and the TINA Process which I discuss in more detail Chapter 6.


235<br />

The 1990s saw the start of the European Union's involvement in infrastructure<br />

policy.... This innovation was far more radical than has generally been suggested by<br />

politicians, researchers or journalists. Historically, the role of public works in the<br />

Member States has far exceeded their specific function … [T]hey also function as a<br />

symbol of the tangible reality of power, which is of crucial importance even in the<br />

modern age. The fact that responsibility for this sector has been conferred on the<br />

Union means that the prospects for the political legitimization of the Union have been<br />

enhanced. … Its new responsibilities mean that it now plays a major role in the<br />

decision-making process at all levels of government in the Member States.<br />

In short, the rise of the TENs also has much to do with the emergence of a<br />

consensus among Member states that their competitiveness is intricately tied to that of the<br />

emerging European Union, and that this Union needed to be vested with additional<br />

powers in order to ensure this ongoing competitiveness at a global scale. The following<br />

discussion of four key spatial storylines surrounding EU transport infrastructure policy in<br />

the 1990s shows how growth and competitiveness considerations continue to win over<br />

redistributive and environmental aims. Some of the identified storylines – Cohesion and<br />

Polycentricity; as well as Missing Links and Bottlenecks, - are partially complementary<br />

and mutually reinforcing. Others are contradictory. Consequently, some of the storylines<br />

end up privileging opposite types of investments. It should also be noted that the<br />

different storylines roughly correspond to different policy directorates within the<br />

Commission. While the Cohesion and Polycentricity storylines are closely aligned with<br />

policies that fall within the competency of DG Regio, the Missing Links and Bottlenecks<br />

storylines are more closely aligned with policies coming out of the DG TREN. Table 6.1<br />

gives an overview of the storylines and the key related policy arenas. The following<br />

sections discuss each storyline in more detail.


236<br />

Table 6.1 Overview of EU Transport Infrastructure Investment Storylines<br />

STORYLINE POLICY ARENA RESPONSIBLE<br />

DIRECTORATE<br />

“Cohesion”<br />

“Polycentricity”<br />

“Missing Links”<br />

“Bottlenecks”<br />

Structural Funds<br />

European Spatial<br />

Development Perspective<br />

Trans-European<br />

Networks,<br />

especially priority projects<br />

DG REGIO<br />

DG TREN<br />

Source: Own compilation<br />

6.3.3 Cohesion<br />

Transport plays a key role in efforts to reduce regional and social disparities in the<br />

European Union and in the strengthening of its economic and social cohesion.<br />

(CEC1999b:1) (Communication from the Commission: Cohesion and Transport)<br />

Cohesion is perhaps the most important spatial storyline in EU policy making. It<br />

represents policy-makers’ recognition of the need to pro-actively counterbalance the<br />

negative effects of increased inter-European competitiveness brought about by the Single<br />

Market and globalization more generally. As a storyline devised to appease the losers of<br />

European integration and enlargement, it represents a formidable challenge that has had<br />

limited success.<br />

Cohesion can be interpreted in various ways, most commonly referring to varying<br />

levels of (economic) stability and/or a process of convergence. Cohesion as a spatial<br />

concept was first written into the Single European Act (SEA) in 1985. It signified a<br />

commitment to promote the development of poorer regions in the EU in order to persuade


237<br />

the poorer member states to agree to the development of the single European market.<br />

The two measures which have received primacy in EU cohesion policies are GDP per<br />

capita and unemployment. Consequently, national and regional cohesion has frequently<br />

been defined in terms of the degree of parity in GDP per capita (also see DIW 2001:9).<br />

So the origins of cohesion policy lie in the realization that the Community should<br />

pay some sort of “integration subsidy” to lower-income regions. EU cohesion policy has<br />

also been characterized as the “flagship of European regulated capitalism” (Hooghe<br />

1998:457). Economic and social cohesion is now one of the fundamental objectives of the<br />

European Union, at least in rhetoric. In Article 2 of the TEU, the Union sets itself the<br />

objective<br />

to promote economic and social progress and a high level of employment and to<br />

achieve balanced and sustainable development, in particular through the creation of an<br />

area without internal frontiers, through the strengthening of economic and social<br />

cohesion and through the establishment of economic and monetary union.<br />

[Emphasis added.]<br />

Cohesion is therefore seen as subservient to achieving progress and sustainability.<br />

In the Treaty on the European Community (TEC), the cohesion objective was been<br />

defined more explicitly as having a very clear spatial dimension (Article 158 TEC, ex<br />

Article 130a):<br />

In order to promote its overall harmonious development, the Community shall develop<br />

and pursue its actions leading to the strengthening of its economic and social cohesion.<br />

In particular, the Community shall aim at reducing disparities between the levels of<br />

development of the various regions and the backwardness of the least favoured regions<br />

or islands, including rural areas. 11<br />

11 Note that this is the very formulation (except for of the mention of the islands) that had been introduced<br />

by the Single European Act in 1985. Back then, however, cohesion was to be achieved through EIB loans,<br />

common Community policies and the coordination of member states policies, i.e. not primarily through the<br />

structural funds, but free market, member state-directed activities supplemented by structural policies<br />

(Allen 2000:249)


238<br />

Note that the terms “development” and “backwardness” are not specifically<br />

defined, however. The Commission has since interpreted the concept as a triple axis<br />

encompassing the physical environment, the business environment and human/social<br />

capital. The main instruments for promoting cohesion within the EU territory have been<br />

the so-called structural funds. They were to address gaps within member states, between<br />

regions, and between social groups. The two funds in this “family of funds” most<br />

important with regard to transport infrastructure investments are the European Regional<br />

Development Fund (ERDF) and the Cohesion Fund. 12<br />

Under the ERDF, the EU provides<br />

funding for transport infrastructures in the EU’s so-called least developed regions<br />

designated as Objective 1. 13 Its overall rationale, laid out in Article 160 TEC, does not<br />

include a specific mention of transport investments:<br />

The European Regional Development Fund is intended to help to redress the main<br />

regional imbalances in the Community through participation in the development and<br />

structural adjustment of regions whose development is lagging behind and in the<br />

conversion of declining industrial regions.<br />

Nevertheless, in practice, the ERDF has provided financial contributions to the<br />

relevant Trans-European Transport Network routes in that area. The Cohesion Fund, by<br />

contrast, was specifically designed to provide assistance in the areas of transport and<br />

environment in the poorest EU countries. (As such, the Cohesion Fund must be seen as a<br />

direct precursor to the pre-accession instrument ISPA). Article 161 of the TEC specifies<br />

that<br />

12 The term “structural funds” was adopted in the late 1980s as a “shorthand term” (Allen 2000) for the<br />

European Regional Development Fund (ERDF), the European Social Fund (ESF), the Guidance Section of<br />

the European Agricultural Guidance and Guarantee Fund (EAGGF). Since their respective addition in<br />

1992 and 1993, respectively, it also includes the Cohesion Fund and the Financial Instrument for Fisheries<br />

Guidance (FIFG).<br />

13 Meaning, as a general rule, that GDP per capita is below 75% of the EU average.


239<br />

A Cohesion Fund set up by the Council … shall provide a financial contribution to<br />

projects in the fields of environment and trans-European networks in the area of<br />

transport infrastructure.<br />

Eligibility under the Cohesion Fund was always determined according to national<br />

economic criteria based on GDP performance, so the future of Cohesion Fund assistance<br />

to Greece, Ireland, Portugal and Spain is threatened by the prospects of Eastern<br />

enlargement. A complex deal was struck in Agenda 2000 by the member governments to<br />

ensure the continuation of both cohesion and enlargement funding from 2000 to 2006.<br />

Allen (2000:264) provides a realist, intergovernmentalist interpretation for the deal.<br />

Bordering on outright cynicism, he notes:<br />

This bargain was probably possible because the structural funds have rather less to do<br />

with real economic cohesion or the eradication of regional disparities than to do with a<br />

modest budgetary redistribution to facilitate the continued development and smooth<br />

running of the EU.<br />

Nevertheless, the official rationale for funding transport infrastructures in the<br />

context of cohesion was the idea that better infrastructure endowment would<br />

automatically make these lagging, often peripherally located, regions more competitive<br />

within the EU territory. That this investment-for-cohesion storyline clearly misrepresents<br />

and oversimplifies the complex effects of transport infrastructure investments on regional<br />

development has already partially been demonstrated during the general discussion over<br />

the relationship between transport and economic development in chapter 2. The<br />

following paragraphs will further elaborate on the contestability of the notion,<br />

concentrating more specifically on the political background of the cohesion storyline. 14<br />

14 Note that the assumption of a straight correlation between transport investment and economic<br />

development is also contradictory to the ambitions of the EU’s new Sustainable Development Strategy,<br />

which explicitly aims at decoupling transport growth from GDP growth.


240<br />

Resources for regional policies from the EU increased almost tenfold from 3.7<br />

billion ECU in 1985 to 33 billion in 1999, amounting to 0.45% of the EU’s total GDP (P.<br />

Martin 1999:11). Although many beneficiary member states nevertheless continue to<br />

argue in this vein, investment-for-cohesion arguments have not been backed this up with<br />

credible results. None of the member states demanded to see these credible numbers,<br />

however, since cohesion funding was not really based on economic development<br />

rationales but on political reasoning. Since deepening integration, i.e. a progressive<br />

implementation of the Single Market, provides an economic threat to the less competitive<br />

regions in the EU, political intuition demanded that subsidies and other economic<br />

incentives be provided for them in order to “sweeten” the deal. Given this political<br />

nature of structural funding at the EU, cohesion policy was therefore never based on any<br />

precise estimations of the true costs for poorer regions of accepting the EMU or further<br />

enlargement (cf. Allen 2000:263). The accession of several lower income countries into<br />

the EU in the 1980s simply made it politically necessary to institute a system of regional<br />

transfers.<br />

Despite this enormous financial commitment, the actual economic justification<br />

behind cohesion policy remains deeply contested. Neo-classical theorists, for example,<br />

since they assume perfect competition, argue that policy interventions in favor of lagging<br />

regions are not necessary because 1) the process of integration itself will sufficiently<br />

accelerate convergence between regions, and 2) even regions with lower levels of<br />

productivity will still gain from trade based on comparative advantage.<br />

This argument is contradicted by new theories of economic geography stressing<br />

endogenous growth (see especially Krugman 1991). These theories emphasize the


241<br />

importance of economies of scale, imperfect competition and the localized nature of<br />

spillover effects. Yet ironically, this new economic geography ends up challenging the<br />

validity of regional transfers in a much more troubling manner, because it implies that<br />

spatial redistribution will diminish competitiveness. The question then becomes whether<br />

cohesion, i.e. a more equalized distribution of economic activity across European space,<br />

is still a desirable goal if it might jeopardize European competitiveness in the long run.<br />

This forces decision-makers to clarify their objectives. Philippe Martin’s (1999):12)<br />

recent EIB prize winning essay poignantly summarizes the key dilemma for economists:<br />

If economies of scale and localized spillovers explain phenomena of increased<br />

regional inequalities, this necessarily implies that efficiency gains … accrue from the<br />

existence of economic agglomeration. The existence of these beneficial effects of<br />

agglomeration suggest rather that, in certain respects, Europe’s economic geography is<br />

insufficiently agglomerated and specialized (for example in comparison with<br />

American geography). It is therefore illogical to claim that the diminution of regional<br />

inequalities supposedly facilitated by regional policies will generate efficiency gains at<br />

pan-European level. To oppose concentration and geographical specialization is also<br />

to renounce their beneficial effects.<br />

According to this rationale, pursuing cohesion ultimately means foregoing the<br />

very benefits that urban and regional agglomerations provide. In other words, although<br />

hugely problematic from an equity perspective, the argument is that Europe as a whole<br />

may be better off (macro-)economically if it keeps concentrating infrastructure<br />

investments in the Blue Banana core of Europe, with certain peripheral exceptions.<br />

Martin is thus making an interesting efficiency argument that the EU, for political<br />

reasons, could never officially heed. 15<br />

15 It should be noted, however, that current rethinking of regional policy as a whole does not necessarily<br />

challenge the sense of using road and rail investments as tools for economic development, since neither<br />

market-led economic integration nor diversification can be achieved without first physically linking the<br />

infrastructures of countries or regions. What it does, challenge, however, is previous simplistic assertions


242<br />

For the last ten years, arguments for the financing of TEN transport networks<br />

have been based on a dual strategy of increasing EU competitiveness and economic and<br />

social cohesion. Unfortunately, this strategy is based on a economic reasoning that is<br />

both internally contradictory and, as is increasingly being pointed out, empirically<br />

dubious. Under the heading “competitiveness and jobs”, the Commission’s 1998 report<br />

on the implementation of the TEN transport guidelines (Commission of the European<br />

Communities 1998d) summarized the TEN strategy as follows:<br />

The rationale for the Community’s Trans-European Network Policy is twofold:<br />

?? Efficient jobs for transport is vital for EU competitiveness, and thus long-term<br />

growth and jobs. EU industry needs efficient transport systems both to keep costs<br />

down and to allow it to provide a good service;<br />

?? To enhance economic and social cohesion by ensuring that peripheral regions are<br />

well connected to EU Networks. Work done for the Cohesion Fund points to a<br />

positive correlation between spending on TEN and private business investment<br />

suggesting a very favorable impact from new infrastructure investment, including<br />

a strong positive effect on employment in the long run.<br />

Based “on very cautious assumptions by Commission services” the paper then<br />

proceeds to estimate that the Transport TEN as a whole, consisting of an investment of<br />

400 billion ECU 16 , could create “between 600.000 to 1.000.000 new permanent jobs, or<br />

2.5. additional jobs per million ECU invested in TEN instead of the average alternative<br />

investment.” The paper, prepared by the Transport Directorate, does not talk about where<br />

exactly this private investment was located in relation to the TEN investments, so nothing<br />

can really be implied as far as spatial cohesion is concerned.<br />

Across town at the Regional Policy Directorate, and at around the same time, the<br />

author(s) of the Commission’s Communication on Cohesion and Transport had much<br />

(also made both by the Commission, see below) that improved road and rail connection automatically<br />

reduce regional disparities.<br />

16 The ECU was the (unminted, virtual) direct predecessor of the Euro, i.e. 1 ECU is equal to 1 €.


243<br />

more precise, less optimistic analysis to offer than their colleagues at the Transport<br />

Directorate, however. The conclusions offered in this Communication are unequivocal<br />

about the possibilities of reducing interregional disparities through transport<br />

infrastructure investments. Taking into account state of the art research about “pump<br />

effects” 17 this report warns of using transport infrastructure investments in peripheral<br />

regions as a panacea for regional development:<br />

It is clear that investment in transport alone will not lead to the reduction of<br />

development disparities. The success of improvements in transport depends on<br />

complementary efforts to ensure that the disadvantaged regional economies are in a<br />

better position to seize the opportunities created. The evidence suggests that in such a<br />

context, carefully selected investments in transport infrastructure in Greece, Spain,<br />

Ireland, and Portugal have had positive long-run effects on private investment and<br />

economic development in the regions, although there may be wide variations in final<br />

impact. [p. 4]<br />

Regarding employment and the efficient operation of the labor market, the<br />

Communication makes it clear that “the key concern here is often not the provision of<br />

new transport infrastructure, but the provision of transport services (particularly public<br />

transport)” (p.5). Ironically considering its title, the 1998 Communication therefore more<br />

or less abandons the whole investment-for-cohesion rhetoric and instead reverts to<br />

arguments in favor of completing the TENs based on a rhetoric of “integration” and<br />

“accessibility.” Referencing two EU research from the mid-nineties, 18 the<br />

Communication summarizes their overall findings as follows:<br />

17 A pump effect is the (counterproductive) removal of resources from structurally weaker and peripheral<br />

regions due to improved accessibility. As for state of the art research, the Communication specifically<br />

refers to the “Study of the socio-economic impact of projects financed by the Cohesion Fund” done by the<br />

London School of Economics (LSE) for the European Commission in 1997.<br />

18 MCRIT. 1994. “Accessibility Study on the Peripheral Regions of the Community Territory: ICON<br />

indicator 1995 and 2020.” Barcelona: MCRIT


244<br />

The completion of TEN in transport clearly represents a necessary condition for<br />

spatial integration and raising accessibility. However, studies confirm that to ensure<br />

the maximum benefit from the TEN their development must be integrated into a<br />

broader strategy.<br />

- the medium-sized cities in centrally located regions and located on the TEN nodes<br />

or corridors tend to obtain the major accessibility gains. Many cities on high-speed rail<br />

and motorways networks can expect a significant improvement in their physical<br />

accessibility;<br />

- the main metropolitan areas are also major beneficiaries from TEN<br />

implementation but to a lesser extent than the medium-sized cities. This reflects the<br />

already well developed transport infrastructure in those regions.<br />

- for peripheral and remote regions to gain the maximum benefit from the TEN,<br />

complementary investment in secondary networks will be required.<br />

(Commission of the European Communities 1999b:6, my emphasis)<br />

Hidden in this paragraph is perhaps the frankest admission in official EU<br />

documents that Trans-European Networks in and of themselves reinforce existing<br />

distributions and tend to be localized around key nodes. Insightful as it is, one should not<br />

overstate the importance of this Communication, however. Communications mainly<br />

serve the purpose of clarifying Commission thinking on a particular issue at a particular<br />

time, but there is no direct political commitment resulting from them, and its conclusions<br />

are not necessarily shared by all members of the Commission. 19<br />

Nevertheless its rhetoric<br />

is indicative. The Second Report on Economic and Social Cohesion recently released by<br />

the Commission also explicitly states that infrastructure endowment is “a necessary, but<br />

not sufficient condition for the economic development and competitiveness of a region”<br />

(Commission of the European Communities 2001e:49). So, in the end, the Brussels-<br />

19 Also, since there was no normal transition from the last administration to the present one, but rather a<br />

complete changeover resulting from allegations of corruption against many previous Commissioners, even<br />

internal commitments to previous Communications within the Commission are weak in this case. In the<br />

case of the 1998 Communication on Cohesion and Transport, it was already characterized as “mainly<br />

forgotten” by DG Regio staff in the spring of 2001, although the person who wrote it has since become<br />

more influential within DG Regio.


245<br />

based European Federation for Transport and Environment (T&E) is justified in accusing<br />

EU regional policy makers of adhering to erroneous beliefs. As they summarize:<br />

Investing in transport infrastructure is frequently assumed to provide large-scale<br />

economic and employment benefits. So much so that large proportions of EU and<br />

national budgets set aside for regional assistance or economic regeneration are devoted<br />

to transport infrastructure. Empirical evidence to support this general assumption is,<br />

however, notable by its absence. A recent overview by a panel of leading experts in<br />

this field has concluded that there are in fact no automatic economic or<br />

employment benefits from such spending on transport. Yet decision makers, and<br />

the funding systems they have developed, continue to rely on the assumption that there<br />

are automatic benefits. The Standing Advisory Committee on Trunk Road Assessment<br />

(SACTRA) in the UK reviewed all the questions related to Transport and Economy.<br />

They found that benefits from transport projects may be limited, they may go to the<br />

already well off, or there may not even be any benefits. The assumptions and<br />

prejudices held by Europe’s decision makers are, in fact, incorrect.<br />

(T&E 2000:iii, all emphases in the original) 20<br />

Accessibility has since often been used as a substitute term for spatial cohesion in<br />

EU literature. Calls for parity of access provide welcome, intuitive justifications for<br />

infrastructure investments in peripheral regions. More generally, putting an emphasis on<br />

the territorial dimensions of cohesion is a convenient way for the Commission to sidestep<br />

a decision for either more rural/peripheral or more urban/core investments, a touchy<br />

and contested subject within the administration. And in the end, for many in the regional<br />

policy directorate, both urban and regional infrastructure investments are no more<br />

important to achieving cohesion than, for example, environmental protection investments<br />

or gender programs.<br />

In sum, cohesion as a general concept is an ongoing storyline within EU policymaking.<br />

Whether the resulting EU programs preferably stress its spatial, economic, or<br />

social aspects in part depends on political rationalizations of the moment. Over the<br />

course of the last few years, the scale has tipped somewhat in favor of a social cohesion


246<br />

rhetoric, even within EU funding programs. 21 Rumford (2000:183), on the other hand,<br />

makes a consistent argument that in the wake of neo-liberal policy-making in Europe, the<br />

primary conceptualization of cohesion even “has become detached from its redistributive<br />

origins and incorporated in a discourse of competitiveness and growth.” In the case of<br />

transport infrastructure investments, investment-for-cohesion arguments attempting to<br />

avoid the “competitiveness trap” are now most frequently put forth in conjunction with<br />

calls for improved accessibility and for the “completion” of the TENs even in remote<br />

regions. These aims are in conflict with neo-liberal macroeconomic efficiency<br />

arguments, however, which would instead call for a greater differentiation of European<br />

spaces based on specialized divisions of labor and regional competitiveness, and hence<br />

for a subsequent concentration of resources in already competitive places. In the wake of<br />

this line of argumentation, the emphasis of cohesion funding then shits from a focus on<br />

peripheral, lagging regions within Cohesion countries (i.e. upgrading of rural roads and<br />

general modernization of infrastructure inside an already underprivileged member state)<br />

towards a modernization of key, national-level infrastructures so that these Cohesion<br />

countries might be more competitive with regard to other EU member states. This<br />

problem of these different geographical scales of under-privilege, and the related internal<br />

inconsistency of the cohesion story-line, will come to haunt us once again when we take a<br />

20 Note the reliance on expert opinion, which also makes this an exemplary statement for reflexive<br />

modernization discourse. Also see Chapter 4.<br />

21 For example, the Commission’s 1998 Social Action Programme asserts that:<br />

The . . . programme's point of departure is that economic and social progress go hand in hand and that<br />

the purpose of economic progress is to raise people's standard of living, against the background of a<br />

balanced macro-economic strategy. Social policy should promote a decent quality of life and standard<br />

of living for all in an active, inclusive and healthy society that encourages access to employment, good<br />

working conditions and equality of opportunity. (CEC 1998, as quoted in Fainstein 2001:3).<br />

There is a rapidly growing literature that uses the term cohesion in the sense of inclusiveness, stressing<br />

issues such as social capital and governance. For an good overview of this literature, see Fainstein (2001).


247<br />

look at the situation in the Eastern candidate countries and the enlargement-related<br />

funding.<br />

6.3.4 Polycentricity<br />

The concept of polycentric development has to be pursued, to ensure regionally<br />

balanced development, because the EU is becoming fully integrated in the global<br />

economy. Pursuit of this concept will help to avoid further excessive economic and<br />

geographic concentration in the core area of the EU.<br />

European Spatial Development Perspective (ESDP) (1999h):20<br />

The concept of polycentricity is intimately bound up with attempts to<br />

reconceptualize and ultimately reshape the spatial structure of urban hierarchies in<br />

Europe.<br />

The difficulty to disentangle rhetorical vision, analytical content and<br />

prescriptive policy elements connected to different concepts of polycentricity<br />

(particularly with regard to the ESDP) has already been variously discussed in the<br />

literature (e.g. Albrechts 2001; Bailey and Turok 2001; Copus 2001; Kloosterman and<br />

Musterd 2001; Krätke 2001; van Houtum and Legendijk 2001; Davoudi 2001a). Like<br />

cohesion, the polycentricity-storyline is based on the key insight that Europe needs a<br />

more equal distribution of globalization and integration gains than is presently the case.<br />

Richardson and Jensen (2000:505) correctly note that “the construction of EU spatial<br />

discourse is conditioned by several mega trends: the globalized market, the emergence of<br />

the competitive city, and the culture of mobility” and that the resulting reframing of cities<br />

is guided by visions of “transcending spatial distances across Europe.” 22<br />

In the late<br />

1980s, researchers at the French spatial planning agency DATAR presented an image of<br />

22 In the related article, Richardson and Jensen identify mobility and polycentric development as central<br />

themes in the European Spatial Development Perspective. Note, however, that what they identify as a<br />

“mobility discourse” is less directly related to infrastructure investments but more attributable to a general<br />

“culture of mobility” that aims at “transcending spatial distances.”


248<br />

European space that has since become ingrained in the minds of many researchers and<br />

decision-makers. They conceived of European space as being dominated by an economic<br />

backbone reaching from London across the channel through the Benelux countries,<br />

Northern France, Switzerland and Southern Germany to Northern Italy. This economic<br />

backbone (dorsale), also variously defined as the heart of Europe, became known as the<br />

Blue Banana (figure 6.3). 23<br />

Blue Banana maps sometimes recognize other important<br />

agglomerations in Europe, but they all they very clearly divide European space into a<br />

core and several peripheries (finisterres), which are often shaded in dark. Ironically, the<br />

catchy Blue Banana image was used by the French spatial analysts precisely in order to<br />

point out the need to develop alternative, more polycentric structures. This desire to<br />

indicate such core-periphery connections, and to indicate a hierarchy of linkages, is<br />

clearly visible in some of the less publicized Banana representations (see figure 6.4).<br />

Nevertheless, the main effect was rather antithetical to the supposed aim of promoting<br />

polycentricity: cities outside the dorsale seemed suddenly doomed as losers simply<br />

because of their location. The Blue Banana became the main metaphor for an<br />

economically divided Europe. The image has proven very difficult to undo, in part<br />

because there is some empirical truth to it. (The highest GDP per capita income regions,<br />

for example, do indeed fall within the banana.)<br />

23 What made the Banana blue? I assume that this was the color used in the original maps produced by<br />

Brunet et al in their 1989 DATAR study, but I was unable to find the original, colored maps to confirm this<br />

with certainty.


249<br />

Figure 6.3 The Blue Banana I: An Image Ingrained<br />

Source: Brunet, (1989, as reprinted in NSPA 2000)<br />

Figure 6.4 Blue Banana Maps Focusing on Peripheral Regions & Urban Linkages<br />

Source: IGARUN, as reprinted in ECMT (1995a), and ECMT (1995a)


250<br />

Probably the most successful counter-image to the Blue Banana was developed by<br />

Kunzmann and Wegener (1991) at the University of Dortmund. They argued that instead<br />

of a banana, one should instead conceive of European space as of a “European Bunch of<br />

Grapes” (figure 6.5). The image successfully evokes the notion of a polycentric Europe,<br />

yet the metaphor does not deny that urban hierarchies will persist. To keep with the<br />

metaphor: the individual grapes are part of a larger whole, but are not equally large, and<br />

some are juicier and tastier than others. Kunzmann (1998:101) has since justified “the<br />

normative concept of the European Bunch of Grapes as a mental vision for spatial equity<br />

in Europe.”<br />

Figure 6.5 The Blue Banana versus a European Bunch of Grapes<br />

Source: Kunzmann and Wegener, as reprinted in NSPA (2000)<br />

At the level of European policy-making, the storyline of polycentricity finds its<br />

most concise, yet still contradictory, expression in a document that was published, but not<br />

officially adopted, by the European Commission in 1999. The document, the European<br />

Spatial Development Perspective (ESDP) carries the ambitious subtitle “Towards a<br />

Balanced and Sustainable Development of the Territory of the European Union.” Agreed


251<br />

at the Informal Council of Ministers responsible for Spatial Planning in Potsdam in May<br />

1999, it was the result of a multi-year, multi country effort at setting out a future vision<br />

for the development of European space in light of current environmental, social and<br />

economic challenges. The overall ESDP process has been meticulously documented by<br />

Andreas Faludi and Bas Waterhout (, 2002 #1199, also see Faludi 2001a) and need not be<br />

recounted here. What concerns us here are some of its key contents and rationales. The<br />

ESDP was developed following the adoption of the so-called Leipzig Principles by<br />

European ministers in 1994. The principles call for: a) development of a balanced and<br />

polycentric urban system and a new urban-rural relationship, b) securing parity of access<br />

to infrastructure and knowledge, and c) sustainable development, prudent management<br />

and protection of nature and cultural heritage (ESDP 1999:11, also see Faludi 2000:8).<br />

Interestingly, the ESDP does not fall into the trap of claiming that Trans-European<br />

Networks will contribute to social and economic cohesion. The rhetoric is instead clearly<br />

oriented towards urban competitiveness. The ESDP recognizes that a large part of the<br />

EU transport investments are concentrated on high-speed railway lines connecting major<br />

conurbations and that cities close to high speed stops will profit most from these<br />

investments. The ESDP’s additional justification that “high-speed lines may offer an<br />

incentive to shift increasing shares of traffic to the railways, thus helping to relieve road<br />

congestion and improve the environment” is both highly speculative and overly<br />

optimistic considering current trends. The ESDP does recognize, however, that<br />

“increases in traffic can no longer be managed by expansion of road infrastructure alone”.<br />

The ESDP insists that “spatial development policy and urban development measures have<br />

a role to play” (all quotes on p.14). The presented perspective (its creators are adamant


252<br />

that the ESDP be not understood as a master plan!), however, remains problematic. Both<br />

centrality and urbanity, as well as their complementary concepts peripherality and rurality<br />

remain contested notions within the ESDP (Richardson and Jensen 2000; Copus 2001). 24<br />

In the end, the greatest challenge is related to the fact that the storyline of<br />

polycentricity entails very different visions at different levels of planning. 25<br />

As Simin<br />

Davoudi (2001a:2) concludes in her recent study on polycentricity in European spatial<br />

planning: “Despite its widespread currency, the concept is not supported by clear<br />

definition, robust theoretical framework and rigorous empirical analysis. Hence,<br />

polycentricity means different things to different people.” Davoudi herself distinguishes<br />

the use and adaptation of the concept at three different spatial scales: intra-urban, interurban,<br />

and inter-regional. Which, however, is the most legitimate Pan-European<br />

interpretation of polycentricity? This question still remains largely unresolved. Stefan<br />

Krätke (2001:107) provides a basic definition of a polycentric system as a “system in<br />

which a whole series of ‘high-ranking’ location centres exist side by side with a large<br />

number of small and medium sized towns and cities,” and he finds that such a polycentric<br />

urban system is “especially relevant in the pan-European perspective.” The difficulty,<br />

however, as Krätke himself correctly asserts, is that “both polycentric and monocentric<br />

24 Maps are conspicuously absent in the ESDP document, precisely because of their controversiality. In<br />

particular, a map in the 1997 Noordwijk draft on “accessibility, infrastructure and transport” was removed<br />

from the final draft because it was not strictly congruent with priorities indicated in the EU’s officially<br />

agreed TEN network plans.<br />

25 Note also the threefold definition of polycentric spatial development in the Study Programme on<br />

European Spatial Planning, see SPESP (1999) and http://www.mcrit.com/spesp/SPESP_REPORT/<br />

2.2.Summary.pdf):<br />

The Concept of polycentricity has at least three meanings in the context of European spatial planning<br />

and regional geography. At the scale of Europe as a whole (inter-regional), the possibility of developing<br />

multiple dynamic growth zones across Europe, to challenge the tendencies for a strong core region to<br />

which other part of the territory are peripheral. … At the scale of the territory (intra-regional), the<br />

situation where there are multiple urban centers, often interconnected, rather than a single dominant<br />

centre … At the scale of the urban agglomeration (intra-urban). This refers to the multiplicity of nodal


253<br />

urban systems are to be found in the individual member states and in eastern central<br />

European countries [and that] the applicability of the notion … to the whole EU needs<br />

further discussion” (p.107). Several Scandinavian countries, for example, are outright<br />

sceptical of the concept (Bengs and Böhme 1998).<br />

Without resolving the issue of choosing between multiple definitions, Peter Hall<br />

(n.d.)nevertheless provides an excellent summary of the different possible interpretations<br />

of the concept at the European, inter-regional, intra-regional and inter-urban levels:<br />

The central word, polycentric, needs to be carefully defined: … At the global level,<br />

polycentric refers to the development of alternative global centres of power. … Within<br />

a specifically European context, therefore, one meaning of a polycentric policy is to<br />

divert some activities away from "global" cities like London (and perhaps Paris) to<br />

"sub-global" centres. … At a finer geographical scale, however, polycentricity can<br />

refer to the outward diffusion from either of these levels of city to smaller cities within<br />

their urban fields or spheres of influence. … Specifically, the general principle should<br />

be to guide decentralised growth, wherever possible, on to a few selected development<br />

corridors along strong public transport links. … In the more remote rural regions, …<br />

the pursuit of polycentricity must have yet another dimension: to build up the potential<br />

of both "regional capitals" in the 200,000-500,000 population range …, and smaller<br />

"county towns" in the 50,000-200,000 range. … Again, but on a smaller scale, the<br />

growth of such centres could be accompanied by a limited degree of deconcentration<br />

to even smaller rural towns within easy reach. It is a complex strategy. 26<br />

In sum, the storyline of polycentricity continues to hold something in stock for<br />

everyone, which means that EU decision-makers wishing to justify high-speed rail<br />

connections between national capitals are as justified to do so in the name of polycentric<br />

urban development as are regional policy-makers arguing for improved road connections<br />

between secondary cities. The storyline of polycentricity fits the EU’s general<br />

framework of ecological modernization quite well. Its rhetoric is firmly set within an<br />

points within large urban areas, which challenge traditional notions of cities focused around their city<br />

centers.<br />

26 Excerpted from Hall, Peter (n.d.), Christaller for a Global Age: Redrawing the Urban Hierarchy, Section<br />

“Towards a spatially integrated approach,” available under http://www.lboro.ac.uk/gawc/rb/rb59.html


254<br />

overall context of competitive European cities and regions which each pursue individual<br />

growth strategies.<br />

6.3.5 Missing Links<br />

TEN-T as a policy has been around for a long time, developed from the “missing<br />

links” and the European Round Table, and all this kind of business, you know.<br />

Brussels Bureaucrat, quoted in Richardson 2000<br />

The Missing Link storyline is predominately industry-created and represents a<br />

masterpiece in infrastructure investment lobbying. As preceding discussions have shown,<br />

EU transport infrastructure funding was obviously not backed up by unequivocal<br />

economic reasoning. So how could the TENs so quickly advance from a mere paper tiger<br />

to a multi-billion Euro investment program? How is it that the EU was willing to commit<br />

billions of Euros in funds to a program that did not guarantee economic returns? The<br />

explanation is that decisions were highly political. But it was also not simply a matter of<br />

income transfers, as was indicated by realist interpretations in the case of cohesion<br />

funding. The rapid adoption of the TENs concept in the early 1990s is primarily due to<br />

their timeliness and due to the ability of the concept to respond to urgent industry and<br />

high-level political needs. The pro-investment infrastructure & construction lobby and<br />

the EU joined forces on the idea of the TENs. In some ways, it may be even more<br />

accurate to say that most official European Union transport infrastructure investment<br />

proposals, and the priority Trans-European Network projects in particular, originated as<br />

industry lobby proposals that were only later transformed into EU policy. There are<br />

several key reports prepared for the European Roundtable of Industrialists (ERT) which<br />

resemble future Commission proposals in startling ways.


255<br />

In particular, ERT’s 1984 report called “Missing Links – Upgrading Europe’s<br />

Transborder Ground Transport Infrastructure: A Report for the Roundtable of European<br />

Industrialists,” outlined three specific proposals for a “Channel link between England and<br />

France,” a “Scanlink” plan for road and rail connections in Scandinavia, and a<br />

“transEuropean network of high-speed trains.” This report urged the EU and private<br />

partners to spend billions of dollar of investments on these TEN precursor projects, which<br />

it claimed were economically highly justified projects. The glossy report (black and<br />

white copies are available at no charge from the Roundtable’s Paris or London offices)<br />

contains the following stunning note in an appendix:<br />

The working group aimed to provide a concise and readable report. For this reason,<br />

data sources and references are conspicuously absent from the text, charts and tables.<br />

The group’s report is compiled from the following written [internally commissioned]<br />

submissions and reports: [List reports] The “pedigree” of the facts and figures quoted<br />

in the “Missing Links” report is finely detailed in the written submissions and reports<br />

listed above. Questions on the pedigree of facts and figures should be addressed to<br />

Michael Hinks-Edwards at the Roundtable Secretariat Paris Office (see address<br />

below).<br />

In other words: the bold ERT proposal was based on data that is neither<br />

independently accessible nor verifiable. Upon request, the ERT is willing to answer<br />

questions on the pedigree, but not provide hard copies of the document itself.<br />

The similarity of even this early proposal with the list of TEN priority projects<br />

adopted ten years later at the Essen Summit in 1994 is striking. Not only did the 1994<br />

EU list end up including the Channel tunnel and the Oeresund road-rail bridge as<br />

individual priority projects, but both were also integrated into a network of high-speed<br />

rail links that picked up most of the connections originally proposed by ERT ten years<br />

earlier (also see figures 6.6 and 6.7).


256<br />

Figure 6.6 Missing Links I: The ERT Vision (1984)<br />

Source: Cover of European Round Table of Industrialists (1984)<br />

Figure 6.7 Missing Links II: The EU TEN Priority Projects (1994)<br />

Source: Map on the EIB website (www.eib.org)


257<br />

ERT soon created the myth that “not only are such projects desirable in terms of<br />

their economic and social impact, but they are affordable, and can be profitable,<br />

environmentally acceptable and financeable without heavy extra commitments to public<br />

spending” (p.1). 27<br />

Corporate watchdog organizations such as ASEED Europe<br />

acknowledge the immense success of the ERT in influencing future EU transport policy.<br />

As Doherty and Hoedeman (1994:137) note:<br />

Through its intensive lobbying of European transport ministers, and also the support of<br />

French Prime Minister Laurent Fabius, the ERT was astonishingly successful in<br />

introducing European power brokers to its vision of a future infrastructure. In 1985,<br />

Volvo’s Pehr Gyllenhammer could report to ERT members that the Italian<br />

government, “on behalf of all the ministers of transportation within the community, is<br />

referring to the Missing Links as a master plan for European infrastructure.”<br />

Other researchers have made the same point. Tim Richardson (1997:337) also<br />

provides a strong case that decisions were influenced by the privileged access that<br />

industry decision-makers had to key Commission working groups:<br />

Proposals for the Trans-European Road Network … were developed by the Motorway<br />

Working Group (MGW) of the Commission’s Transport Infrastructure Committee<br />

[which included] a number of private sector interests including the European Round<br />

Table (ERT), the Association des Constructeurs Europeens d’Automobile, and the<br />

International Road Transport Union. The Committee was overwhelmingly dominated<br />

by transport and infrastructure interests, with a notable absence of environmental<br />

interests. […] It appears that the debate within this key decision-making arena was<br />

largely political. The institutional power of the infrastructure lobby demonstrated here<br />

was strengthened by ready access to top-ranking EC and member-state politicians.<br />

Dick Richardson (1997:55) chimes in almost verbatim. In reminding us that the<br />

consequences of the TERNs are in direct contradiction to the EU’s own environmental<br />

27 In fact, ERT claimed, some of the link projects:<br />

could be financed in very large measure by the private sector. If governments were prepared to set the<br />

right investment climate in terms of fiscal incentives and operating licences, the money could be raised.<br />

… Although Europe has become culturally programmed to see large transport infrastructure projects as<br />

the preserve of government, there is no reason why this should be so. (ibid)


258<br />

policy, he also takes the critique one step further, once again contrasting EU rhetoric<br />

versus reality:<br />

In reality, at the European level as well as at the global level, environmental policy is<br />

made and implemented in terms of the vested interests in government and industry<br />

who wish to consolidate their power and follow the path of economic growth. For<br />

example, the TERN plan was based on proposals made by the Motorways Working<br />

Group […]. The fact that the consequences of TERN, in terms of the production of<br />

greenhouse gases such as carbon dioxide, can be considered to be in direct<br />

contravention of the EU’s commitments in the Framework Convention on Climate<br />

Change at Rio did not even enter the equation.<br />

The industry lobby itself was somewhat divided between promoters of high speed<br />

rail and old-fashioned automobile lobbyists. But since all of them were arguing for<br />

stepping up infrastructure investments, the demands were not presented in a dissenting<br />

fashion but rather as a multi-modal package. Nevertheless, the director of the German<br />

automobile industry lobby, Dieckmann (1995:103-106) has a very clear slant to his<br />

“missing links” storyline, worth quoting at length:<br />

Missing links in the European road network impact most severely on national traffic<br />

flows because this is where the bulk of the movements occur. … The TERN [Trans-<br />

European Road Network] proposals are a first attempt to put pan-European road<br />

planning on a rational basis. …. Nevertheless far greater attention seems to be given to<br />

the creation of a European high-speed rail network. Though the creation of such a<br />

network undoubtedly offers a number of advantages, it will only account for a fraction<br />

of the movements of goods and people in Europe once it is completed. …. This<br />

resurgence in rail-oriented investment contrasts sharply with rail’s share in traffic<br />

volumes. As pointed out earlier it will have negative effects on the sustainability of<br />

the transport system. This policy is not rational. It again raises the question how<br />

serious governments are about reducing pollution, accidents and casualties on the<br />

road. The problem of financing the missing links in the European road network could<br />

easily be solved if railways in Europe succeeded in cutting their costs by about onethird,<br />

thereby reducing the need for subsidies. Over a ten-year period these savings<br />

would provide about 120 billion ECU, which is the sum needed to create a European<br />

road network.


259<br />

Regardless of these different modal biases, joint ERT lobbying for the missing<br />

links was heavily stepped up before the passing of the Maastricht Treaty, with three more<br />

ERT publications further underlining previous calls for Trans-European networks.<br />

Lobbying proved successful. Already two years after the ERT proposal, the European<br />

Conference of Ministers of Transport published its sketch-like map of Europe showing a<br />

list of “missing links” in European road and rail infrastructure (figure 6.8).<br />

Figure 6.8 Missing Links III: The ECMT Version<br />

Source: ECMT as reprinted in Turro (1999)<br />

Around the time of the Maastricht Treaty, the OECD (OECD 1992:93) also<br />

chimed in with efficiency arguments for completing key infrastructure links, linking the<br />

“missing links” rhetoric with the follow-up storyline of “bottlenecks” but interestingly<br />

also warning that it is also possible to create too much infrastructure:


260<br />

A bottleneck or a missing link result in less efficiency for the whole network. One<br />

small link investment can therefore have a dramatic effect on logistics efficiency,<br />

while another one creates overcapacity.<br />

Despite the serious objections to the TEN on both environmental and social, and<br />

even on economic grounds, several important arguments worked in favor of the TENs<br />

from the point of view of the Commission. Besides the strong pressures from the<br />

industry in the form of the Round Table of European Industrialists, there was internal<br />

pressure in the form of what Turro (1999:102) calls the “bicycle theory.” According to<br />

this theory, the European Union is constantly forced to “keep pedaling to avoid falling<br />

off” i.e. it has to push and explore new areas of cooperation and increase political and<br />

economic cooperation in order to keep the union alive. And in the particular context of<br />

the early 1990s, embarking on “Missing Infrastructure Links” and “Trans-European<br />

Networks” served several strategic objectives for the Commission: First, it provided a<br />

new “safe” field of cooperation at a time where it was too early to seriously push<br />

common defense and foreign policy or monetary unification. Second and more<br />

important, Trans-European infrastructures could be used to justify an important increase<br />

in the Community budget and a reduction of the excessive share of the overall budget that<br />

was spent on the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP). Since the implementation of the<br />

projects would remain a national responsibility, no substantial expansion of the EU<br />

bureaucracy was needed. Turro (1999:103) also points out that<br />

under these conditions, the transfer of investment from the national to the Community<br />

budget could be of interest to Finance Ministers needing to improve the appearance of<br />

their public debt and national deficit figures to comply with the EMU conditions. …<br />

[T]he TENs concept had the rare virtue of combining national and common interests<br />

and to be timely and mostly non-controversial. … This explains its quick progress in<br />

relation to the normal pace of European policy-building.


261<br />

Once the “Missing Links” storyline was in full force, its promoters did not have to<br />

even bother pretending to work towards a more equitable, more sustainable Europe. In a<br />

report commissioned for the European Parliament, Piodi (1997:24-25) notes that the<br />

Christopherson Report in fact argues that “improved access to the central poles of activity<br />

of the Union will help boost competitiveness of the regions concerned and the<br />

undertakings located there” which he correctly unveils as meaning that the TENs, from<br />

their outset, were going to fundamentally contradict EU cohesion development goals:<br />

[T]he Christophersen report frankly admits the existence of a circumstance which has<br />

in some circles been seen as a breach of Article 129b of the Treaty, namely the priority<br />

given to infrastructure creation in the Union's central regions rather than in the<br />

peripheral and island regions.<br />

The same dynamic continued when the EU started to address the issue of<br />

enlarging the TENs eastward. Very quickly, the rhetoric switched from a talk about<br />

network extensions to that of corridor expansion. Long before the Transport<br />

Infrastructure Needs Assessment (TINA) for the candidate countries was finished in<br />

1999, the EU and the Candidate countries had already agreed on a set of Pan-European<br />

Corridors who were to receive priority assistance. So once again, the priority focus was<br />

on privileged “missing links” representing major trade routes between the various capital<br />

cities, and not on an integrated, sustainable development of the networks as a whole. The<br />

EU attempted to sell the corridors as a forerunner for a larger network, but the reality<br />

remains that these links will skew the network and further reshape European space to<br />

improve accessibility mostly between key links, and not equally across space:<br />

These ten pan-European transport corridors are intended to improve trade and mobility<br />

within Europe. The concept of the transport corridors is based on the same content and<br />

objectives as the trans-European transport networks within the EU and represents the<br />

forerunner of a Pan-European transport network. The investment requirement for these


262<br />

projects is in the region of ECU 25 to 30 billion. In the EU budget, ECU 1.8 billion<br />

was made available for the years 1995 to 1999, including 75% for the priority projects.<br />

(European Parliament 1999:6)<br />

In sum, the “Missing-links” storyline is the one that most honestly reveals the key<br />

rationale behind EU transport infrastructure investments, namely to improve conditions<br />

for business and trade between the most powerful, most competitive urban<br />

agglomerations in Europe.<br />

6.3.6 Bottlenecks<br />

Unless infrastructure is interconnected and free of bottlenecks, to allow the physical<br />

movement of goods and persons, the internal market and the territorial cohesion of the<br />

Union will not be fully realized.<br />

EU White Paper “European Transport Policy for 2010: Time to Decide.” 2001:50<br />

The bottleneck storyline is not a new one in EU transport policy, but it has<br />

recently reappeared with vigor in the Commission’s new White Paper on the Common<br />

Transport Policy (Commission of the European Communities 2001f). In the section on<br />

infrastructure policy, the almost exclusive focus on the issue of bottlenecks in this<br />

document is stunning. In some ways, it is a variation of the “Missing Links” storyline.<br />

And again, the industry is ahead of the Commission in terms of setting the stage for the<br />

ensuing rhetoric. In the mid- to late-1990s, the so-called European Centre for<br />

Infrastructural Studies (ECIS) in Rotterdam published two major studies on the ”State of<br />

European Infrastructure” (1996) and on “Bottlenecks in the European Transport<br />

Networks” (1999).<br />

The Bottlenecks-storyline aims at creating a strong sense of urgency. Its major<br />

implication is that there are congested infrastructures that need to be “unblocked”. In its


263<br />

most simple form, it is an unqualified cry for infrastructure expansion. The idea is that<br />

the free flow of goods, and by extension, the competitiveness of the entire European<br />

economy, is hindered by the limited capacity of Europe’s roads, rail lines, waterways and<br />

air routes. In complete disregard for the EU’s Sustainable Development Strategy, which<br />

was published the same year, the new Transport White Paper is content in simply<br />

focusing on curing the symptoms (i.e. bottlenecks) rather than address transport problems<br />

from a more comprehensive, growth-managing perspective. It simply states that the<br />

“transport boom is outstripping economic growth” and that this is “posing a major<br />

problem.” The White Paper’s understanding of the environmentally sustainable policy<br />

developed at the Gothenburg European Council is also limited: it supposedly only<br />

“underlined” the need “to tackle rising levels of congestion and encourage the use of<br />

environmentally friendly modes” (p.50). As for the latter, this appears to be defined as<br />

anything apart from highway funding including multimodal projects, high-speed rail, sea<br />

terminals and airports. Already in the introductory paragraphs of the section, the writers<br />

of the White Paper (i.e. DG TREN) entirely abandon even the slightest nod towards stateof-the-art<br />

transport policy - which would advise better management rather than building<br />

after demand – (see quote at the beginning of the section).<br />

The White paper suggests concentrating a major share of future TEN resources on<br />

“unblocking the major routes” i.e. the existing 14 Essen TEN priority projects as well as<br />

a select number of new “special” projects. There is simply no more talk of equal<br />

distribution of benefits from infrastructures in this paper. The proposed two-stage<br />

revision speaks for itself:


264<br />

The first stage in 2001 … should concentrate on eliminating bottlenecks on the routes<br />

already identified as priorities for absorbing the traffic flows generated by<br />

enlargement, particularly in frontier regions, and improving access to outlying areas.<br />

… [For] the second state in 2004 [t]he idea is to concentrate on a primary network<br />

made up of the most important infrastructure for international traffic and cohesion on<br />

the European continent.<br />

In the entire paper, there is no precise definition of what exactly constitutes a<br />

“bottleneck.” A section entitled “foreseeable bottlenecks”, the White Paper includes<br />

missing border links, single track rail lines, lack of bridges, and limitations on certain<br />

waterways. Other sections speak of urban ring roads. In the end, the clear tenor is to<br />

accommodate rather than manage growth. The European Environment Agency (2001:30)<br />

strongly criticizes this, giving a negative overall assessment to EU transport investments<br />

practices, even noting that the fact that “decisions on transport infrastructure are still<br />

made mainly as a response to problems of traffic bottlenecks [is a] reactive approach<br />

[that] favours extension of the road infrastructure.” It would be naïve to pretend that<br />

bottlenecks can always be addressed though means other than infrastructure expansion.<br />

What is problematic however, is that the Commission should be focusing so vicariously<br />

on so-called international bottlenecks in relation to the TENs, since the actual projects<br />

hiding behind this designation are often the very same large scale industry-lobbied<br />

“missing links” that did not get built (yet) during the 1990s. Here, at a recent conference<br />

on the release of the White Paper, the Secretary General of the ECMT, Jack Short (Short<br />

2001:2) warned the Commission not to overstate the importance of EU funding:<br />

Since a bottleneck is where there are severe problems it is logical that investment<br />

should show high economic rates of return. But it should be understood that<br />

bottlenecks in international traffic might sometimes benefits more from particular<br />

national investments rather than high profile and very expensive international projects.


265<br />

For roads, it might be a bypass round Budapest for example or a particular seed<br />

investment in terminals for combined transport. 28<br />

More importantly, Short reminded his Brussels audience that “bottlenecks are not<br />

all physical” and that “there is a tendency to overdimension projects once they are on the<br />

maps. Motorways or high speed trains are not needed everywhere” (p.3). This comment<br />

is particularly insightful in light of current Pan-European infrastructure plans for the<br />

Central European candidate countries, where ambitions for infrastructure expansion are at<br />

a particularly drastic mismatch with actual funding and planning capabilities, and indeed,<br />

as Short correctly notes, also with actual needs.<br />

Finally, the dramatic resurgence of the bottlenecks storyline also points to another<br />

key issue in need of further discussion, namely the persistent interdependence of Pan-<br />

European and urban interests with regard to infrastructure expansion. Apart from<br />

bottlenecks at natural barriers (e.g. Alpine tunnels) and national borders, congestion is<br />

primarily related to urban densities. This is a circumstance that opens the way for both<br />

cooperation and conflict (see esp. Chapter 7).<br />

6.4 Conclusions: The Challenge of Prioritizing Investments<br />

The difficulties in agreeing on a common European transport policy, of course,<br />

have much to do with the fact that it is difficult to define its prime beneficiaries. From a<br />

public welfare perspective, the key consideration for any investment is the optimal use of<br />

public funds to the greatest possibly benefit of all populations in the affected regions.<br />

One therefore also has to ask the question whether new investment into transport<br />

infrastructures should be the priority strategy at all. Other investments, especially road<br />

28 Note that in the specific case of Budapest, international, and more specifically EU (EIB) involvement in


266<br />

upgrading and maintenance, often promise greater economic returns (World Bank 1996).<br />

Especially in the mature economies of the European Union, it often makes much sense to<br />

concentrate on even other aspects. For example, in order to attract the kind of highly<br />

educated labor force that the new telecommunications and computer industries require,<br />

place-factors such as cultural institutions may be more important than additional access<br />

roads. However, regional interest may collide with national interests here. For example,<br />

local residents may consider an upgrading of the local road or rail system much more<br />

important and preferable than the construction of an additional long-distance freeway<br />

routed through their region, especially if the project cuts though valuable nature reserves.<br />

Yet, national priority projects are typically not based on the specific needs of the regions,<br />

but rather on a more general national master plan. Large-scale links often receive priority<br />

primarily not because they can be justified either through careful cost-benefit analysis or<br />

production function calculations but simply for political reasons. This is even more true<br />

at the Pan-European level.<br />

The demand for new infrastructure or added capacity is of course typically highest<br />

in regions with higher population densities, i.e. in core regions. Since cost-benefit<br />

analyses continue to calculate the bulk of their benefits from time saving from the users,<br />

investments in these more urbanized, higher density core regions will still show greater<br />

benefits than in lower density regions. In other words, if investments were to simply<br />

follow existing demand, then peripheral regions, which are typically more rural in<br />

character, would be unlikely to receive priority investments. There is an obvious<br />

dilemma here and it demonstrates that transport policy has to be developed in consistency<br />

with spatial and regional policies. Despite efficiency arguments favoring investments in<br />

the financing of the ring road has in fact been a crucial and contested issue. See Chapter 8 for details.


267<br />

agglomerations in the core, the EU is likely to continue to be committed to developing<br />

rural and peripheral regions, and will therefore continue to finance rural transport<br />

infrastructures. It should be clear, however, that this is first and foremost a political<br />

commitment, and not an efficiency decision. The problem is that these infrastructures<br />

will be primarily roads. With population and economic activity necessarily being more<br />

dispersed in peripheral regions, higher per capita investments are needed there. And<br />

given current political dynamics, with non-central regions gaining rather than losing<br />

political influence in Brussels, the EU is unlikely to discourage rural development for<br />

efficiency reasons in the near future.<br />

The fact that the key objective of EU cohesion and spatial development policies,<br />

namely to achieve a more balanced distribution of infrastructure across space, is<br />

contradictory to what the EU’s own house bank and main lending institution, the<br />

European Investment Bank, considers state of the art economic rationality, is a deeply<br />

troubling thought. The EIB itself has been the main funding institution for those very<br />

TEN networks that supposedly will be developed “for the benefit of all citizens of the<br />

European Union”. 29<br />

On a more general level, the contrasting storylines explain the recurring dilemma<br />

of all decision-making surrounding large-scale infrastructure: by definition, all “backbone<br />

networks,” be they located along the Blue Banana or along any of the ten chosen Helsinki<br />

Pan-European corridors, privilege connections between large cities and bypass<br />

agglomerations of lesser importance. And the bypass effect is certainly much greater in<br />

29 Much important grant funding for TEN networks particularly in the four lower income EU member<br />

countries has come from the EU Cohesion Fund. However, a much larger part of the TENs was financed<br />

through favorable loans from the EIB, as well as through public-private partnerships and national<br />

government funds.


268<br />

the case of high-speed rail than for roads. This means losers are scattered along the way,<br />

and, according to the British SACTRA 30 experts, even possibly also at of the two ends.<br />

This latter point becomes particularly important when we consider the EU’s ambitions to<br />

extend the TENs into Central and Eastern Europe.<br />

EU decision-making thus remains deeply conflicted and contested. EU transport<br />

sector investments continue to have to satisfy different aims related to growth,<br />

competitiveness, cohesion and sustainability. Environmental concerns often take a back<br />

seat to mainstream economic development interests, and the politically most influential<br />

core regions continue to be able to attract a significant amount of infrastructure funding at<br />

the expense of less economically advanced peripheral areas. The TEN priority projects<br />

fundamentally violate cohesion goals and sustainable development by concentrating<br />

investments in already privileged areas. And despite a rhetorical favoring of rail, the<br />

majority of investments still went towards road projects. (One of the key reasons why<br />

lending and grant making remain so heavily biased towards road is the failing<br />

commitment of the recipient governments to more actively pursue a modal shift towards<br />

rail.) In the cases of the chosen fourteen TEN priority projects, which were determined at<br />

the 1995 Essen Council meeting of the EU, most of the high-profile road and rail projects<br />

were, in fact, long-standing pet industry projects that had been heavily promoted by the<br />

industrial lobby for some time.<br />

Finally and perhaps most importantly, the diminished faith in transport<br />

investments as triggers of economic growth in lagging regions must be seen in the larger<br />

context of the recent reevaluation of the possibilities of regional policy as a whole. In<br />

Europe, empirical evidence in the 1990s has been used to support both supporters and<br />

30 Standing Advisory Committee on Trunk Road Assessment


269<br />

dissenters of the view that regional policies can help poorer regions catch up with<br />

wealthier ones. Many commentators argue that the economic forces leading to an<br />

increasing divergence between regions are simply too strong for regional policies to<br />

counteract them. According to this view, infrastructure investments in poorer regions<br />

appear as pure income transfers that are unlikely to seriously narrow the productivity gap<br />

between poorer and richer regions. In fact, improved transport connections may even<br />

accelerate out-migration in poor regions and thus widen rather than narrow the gap.<br />

Alternatively, one might argue that these types of transfers negatively affect overall<br />

growth. As Philippe Maystadt (2000b:4), the president of the EIB, recently noted:<br />

“Indeed, [regional spending] may lead to lower overall prosperity if it drains resources<br />

from those wealthy and innovative regions that are the main engines of economic growth.<br />

If this is the case, we face a trade-off between equality and growth.”<br />

An increasing number of scholars concerned about the increasing environmental<br />

burden that our transport systems impose upon us would throw in ecology for good<br />

measure, arguing that it is really a three-way trade off. So in the end, we are once again<br />

faced with the fact that the goal of sustainable development, regional or otherwise, is<br />

always struggling to balance at least three often incompatible dimensions: growth, equity<br />

and the environment.


270<br />

Printed on September 21, 2002<br />

Last revised on Sept 15, 2002<br />

PART III: REALITIES<br />

EU Transport Infrastructure<br />

Decision-Making in the Context of<br />

Eastern Enlargement


271<br />

Printed Sunday, November 17, 2002<br />

Last amended Sept 17, 2002<br />

CHAPTER 7<br />

EU Transport Infrastructure Plans for CEE:<br />

From 10 “Priority Corridors” to a<br />

“Backbone Network” for an Enlarged Union<br />

7.1 Introduction..................................................................................................... 272<br />

7.2 EU Plans and Programs for CEE Transport Infrastructures: Overview ......... 276<br />

7.3 From the E-Routes to the Pan-European Transport Corridors........................ 278<br />

7.4 The Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment (TINA) for CEE................. 285<br />

7.4.1 From Politically-Defined Corridors to an Assessed Network?............... 285<br />

7.4.2 Continued Politicking: European versus National Interests ................... 292<br />

7.4.3 Defining the Desired Future: EU Status Quo Defines CEE Needs ........ 294<br />

7.4.4 Network Assessment & Priority Corridors: Contradictory Discourses .. 298<br />

7.5 The Environmental Scoping Exercise on the Warsaw – Budapest Corridor .. 301<br />

7.6 Epilogue: The Proposed Hungarian Amendments to the TINA Network ...... 305<br />

7.7 Conclusions and Consequences ...................................................................... 308


272<br />

7.1 Introduction<br />

Previous chapters demonstrated that development objectives for EU support for<br />

transport infrastructures in member states are internally contradictory, attempting to<br />

simultaneously achieve greater cohesion (i.e. economic convergence) and<br />

competitiveness (economic differentiation and hierarchization) among different EU<br />

regions. Chapter 6 further indicated that EU’s Trans-European Network plans and<br />

related transport infrastructure investment rationales are ultimately dominated by two<br />

powerful storylines, namely the notions of “missing links” and “bottlenecks”. Policymakers<br />

and analysts have not sufficiently assessed the implications of such contradictions<br />

and biases for enlargement-related transport investments. 1<br />

The EU accession literature is<br />

equally unhelpful. Recent books and articles on the EU’s Eastern enlargement do not<br />

give much thought to the transport-specific aspects of accession (compare e.g. Avery and<br />

Cameron 1998; Grabbe and Hughes 1998; Fink Hafner 1999; Smith 2000; Hughes, Sasse<br />

et al. 2001). Moreover, few articles properly acknowledge the problematic fact that<br />

structural assistance for CEE candidate countries is based on a model of structural<br />

assistance that is heavily criticized by regional development experts and Green EU<br />

parliamentarians. 2<br />

To make matters worse, conflicts of interests surrounding EU-CEE<br />

links are more geo-politically complex than in the case of internal EU connections<br />

1 Note that parts of the information assembled in the following sections were collected as part of a two-part<br />

research consulting project for the German Environmental Agency (Umweltbundesamt) which I co-directed<br />

in 1999 and 2000. However, this research project focused exclusively on international transport<br />

infrastructure investment-decision making processes in the Baltic Sea region, and therefore did not include<br />

any information on the Hungarian international corridors and/or investment priorities. More importantly,<br />

the focus of the research was not to analyze European Union transport policy but rather to analyze and<br />

critique the lending activities and mechanisms of the International Financial Institutions active in the Baltic<br />

Sea region (i.e. the World Bank, the EBRD, the EIB and the Nordic Investment Bank). The resulting report<br />

(HELCOM 2000) is therefore partially guilty of the same default.<br />

2 See for example the Hiltner report, a German Green Party position paper on the revision of the Structural<br />

Funds, available on the Green-Party affiliated Heinrich Böll Foundation website (www.boell.de).


273<br />

between member states, and prospects for environmentally-friendly, transparent<br />

infrastructure decision-making are bleaker in the case of the candidate countries given the<br />

dire state of CEE transport infrastructures.<br />

The transport infrastructure investment decision-making process in the CEE<br />

candidate countries must of course be seen in context with the collapse of Communism in<br />

that region, and the transformation from a centrally planned to a market economy. CEE<br />

countries are in various stages of transition, displaying variable degrees of privatization<br />

and decentralization. Economic recession in the 1990s led to a severe reduction in<br />

spending capacities of governments, particularly at the local level. In the area of<br />

transport and land use, socialism left a legacy of non-market based infrastructures, landuses<br />

and (intra-urban) population densities. Before the transition, low price, primarily<br />

rail-based transport was provided by large, publicly-owned and –subsidized companies,<br />

meaning that road networks were comparatively modest in size and relatively<br />

undifferentiated. Also, significant backlogs in infrastructure and equipment maintenance<br />

were already built up during the 1980s. Then, during the 1990s, the rapid rise in<br />

individual motorization, the falling demand for public transport, the emergence of weakly<br />

regulated private vehicle operators and dramatic shifts in urban land uses began to erode<br />

the monopoly position of public transport companies and put them into existential<br />

operational and financial difficulties. Between 1988 and 1996, public transport’s share of<br />

motorized trips fell from 79 to 50% in Poland and from 80 to 52% in Hungary (Pucher<br />

1999:227). By contrast, between 1990 and 1998, motorization levels rose from 276 to<br />

511 cars per 1000 inhabitants in Prague, from 190 to 392 in Warsaw, and from 235 to<br />

313 in Budapest (Mitric 2002). National and local governments are presently struggling


274<br />

to react to a situation of rising levels of traffic congestion, noise, accidents, and pollution<br />

in urbanized areas, as well as ill-maintained and inappropriate regional and long-distance<br />

infrastructures. 3<br />

In such contexts, the pursuit of sustainable transport infrastructure<br />

investments appears as a particularly daunting task.<br />

This chapter looks at two major EU transport sector initiatives that were launched<br />

at the Pan-European level in the mid- to late 1990s just as accession negotiations with the<br />

candidate countries began to pick up steam. First, I take a look at the gestation process<br />

of the ten Pan-European Corridors, the so-called Helsinki Corridors. After that, I will<br />

analyze the Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment (TINA) process for CEE<br />

countries supported by the European Commission. I also include a section on a strategic<br />

assessment effort carried out for the TINA corridor between Warsaw and Budapest. The<br />

presented material on these processes will then provide the setting for the subsequent<br />

case study on EU pre-accession transport infrastructure investments support for Poland<br />

and Hungary in Chapter 8. Note that the European transport ministers’ agreement on the<br />

ten Helsinki Corridors can be considered a “history-making” (Peterson and Bomberg<br />

1999) and therefore internationally binding decision, while the TINA process, despite<br />

3 In fact, pollution from stationary sources, particularly sulphur/SO2 emissions fell drastically after the<br />

transition. Also, due to the economic downturn and the switch from coal to gas in the region, overall<br />

emissions of carbon dioxide, the main greenhouse gas, fell between 1990 and 1995. Since then, this<br />

development has been increasingly offset by transport-related CO2 emissions from road vehicles (European<br />

Environment Agency 2002). In Poland, CO2 emissions from transport rose by 23%, those from road<br />

transport even by 40% between 1988 and 1999. Road transport now accounts for 96% of all CO2<br />

emissions in Poland. Figures are similar for Hungary, although the most rapid increases in motorization<br />

already occurred during the 1980s (Hook 1999:207). Nevertheless, transport-related CO2 emissions still<br />

rose by 10%, and those from road transport by 23% between 1987 and 1999, with road transport now<br />

accounting for 97% of all CO2 emissions in Hungary. See OECD (2002:27). Last but not least, after a<br />

decade of rising death tolls, road safety is now improving again in most CEE countries, including Hungary<br />

and Poland (European Conference of Ministers of Transport (ECMT) 2001).


275<br />

having been an intergovernmental process, remained an effort without official legal<br />

standing inside or outside the EU. 4<br />

One of the overarching objectives of this “realities” part of the study is to attempt<br />

to identify in how far conflicts of interests surrounding particular infrastructure<br />

investments can in fact be linked back to different underlying investment rationales.<br />

Using the international process culminating in the Commission-funded publication of the<br />

Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment (TINA) for the Central European candidate<br />

countries as its case study focus, this chapter reveals the EU’s key underlying rationales<br />

and rationalizations for investing in CEE transport infrastructures. The Pan-European<br />

Corridor process simply demonstrates the primate of power and politics over economic<br />

rationality at the history-making levels of EU decision-making. The TINA process,<br />

however, is more interesting in that it proves to be a perfect example of a rationality-aspower<br />

exercise within the discursive framework of ecological modernization.<br />

The two central propositions for the next two chapters are the Decisional-Power<br />

and the Challenges of Multi-Location Politics Propositions. The Decisional-Power<br />

Proposition assumes that Pan-European Transport Network policies and plans are<br />

primarily designed to satisfy national economic and multi-national corporate interests.<br />

The Multi-Location Politics Proposition is based on the premise that despite being a<br />

powerful Directorate General within the European Commission, the DG responsible for<br />

4 In fact, under the old Transport Commissioner Neil Kinnock, the original plan was supposedly to hold a<br />

ministerial conference on TINA, but due to corruption charges brought against several Commissioners at<br />

the time, all Commissioners had to step down and extensive restructuring followed. The new DG TREN<br />

Commissioners were then more cautious about working towards a ministerial decision. Nevertheless, DG<br />

Transport & Energy representatives planned to elevate the TINA network’s informal status by attaching the<br />

TINA report as an annex to the planned revision of the TEN guidelines, which are formal EU law. Since<br />

these TEN guidelines are part of the so-called transport Acquis, i.e. the transport-specific sections of the<br />

Acquis Communautaire, which form the basis of the accession treaties, they thereby become binding<br />

legislation for the accession countries as well.


276<br />

transport (DG TREN) in fact has limited power to straightforwardly implement its own<br />

transport sector objectives and policies in the candidate countries both because of the<br />

EU’s multi-level governance structure and the importance of additional stakeholders. 5<br />

Meanwhile, previous propositions about “Dominant Discourses” and “Conflicting<br />

Storylines” in EU decision-making also remain relevant for Part III of study, albeit<br />

sometimes with slightly different twists.<br />

7.2 EU Plans and Programs for CEE Transport Infrastructures: Overview<br />

Table 7.1 provides a general overview of the four key initiatives relevant for our<br />

analysis of EU transport-sector infrastructure investments in the CEE candidate countries.<br />

Note that the Helsinki Corridors and the TINA network discussed in this chapter form<br />

part of the so-called “Pan-European Transport Network.” In all, this network consists of<br />

the following components (also see Commission of the European Communities and<br />

Vienna 2000d):<br />

?? The Trans-European Transport Network on the territory of the European Union<br />

(TEN);<br />

?? The ten Pan-European Transport Corridors situated in the acceding countries, in the<br />

NIS and beyond;<br />

?? The TINA network, which is composed of the ten Corridors and the additional<br />

network components within the candidate countries for accession;<br />

?? Four Pan-European Transport Areas (PETrAs) covering Maritime areas;<br />

?? Euro-Asian Links, notably TRACEA (Transport Corridor Europe Caucasus Asia).<br />

The TENs have been discussed in previous sections of this study. Due to<br />

necessary limits in the scope of the present study, neither the PETrAs nor any Euro-Asian<br />

5 The two propositions are quite compatible. Also note that contrary to common misperceptions,<br />

interpreting the EU as a system of multi-level governance does not mean that national leadership and<br />

decision-power necessarily succumb to a diffuse or even unstable hierarchy of influences. As Marks et al.<br />

(1996) note: “The multi-level government model does not reject the view that state executives and state<br />

arenas are important, or that these remain the most important pieces of the European puzzle” (emphasis in<br />

the original).


277<br />

links are investigated in any further detail here. For equal reasons, the Phare/LISF 6<br />

program is also not presented in greater detail in the present study. It was equally beyond<br />

the scope of this study to include a detailed comparative analysis of the transport-sector<br />

loan activities of the “house bank” of the EU, the European Investment Bank (EIB), in<br />

the CEE region, despite the fact that these loans present highly revealing additional<br />

insights with regard to structural, macro-economic rationalities of the European Union. 7<br />

In the end, it is also important to realize that the two major infrastructure plans<br />

discussed in this chapter, the Pan-European Corridors and the TINA Networks, were<br />

based on initiatives dominated by the Commission’s Transport Directorate and by<br />

national transport ministries, while the subsequent ISPA program which disburses the<br />

EU’s pre-accession infrastructure funds in the area of transport is administered by the<br />

Regional Policy directorate, DG REGIO. Throughout the various initiatives, we will<br />

witness varying conflicts of interests not only between the EU and the CEE candidate<br />

countries, but also within different elements of the EU multi-level governance structure,<br />

as well as with other outside actors.<br />

6 LISF stands for Large Scale Infrastructure Facility. It only had a short life-span within the overall Phare<br />

program. The LSIF was conceived in light of the need to restructure the Phare program in order to better<br />

coordinate it with the emerging pre-accessing fund strategy, which culminated in the ISPA fund. In<br />

essence, the LSIF was intended as a trial-run for the ISPA grant program.<br />

7 Suffice to say that while in theory, the EIB is an EU institution accountable to both general EU policy<br />

directives and specific investment priorities, in practice, EIB investments are guided by a curious mix of<br />

“bankability”-considerations related to rationales derived from neo-classical economic theory and more<br />

political considerations relating to the EIB’s overall mission of promoting European integration. (The latter<br />

are mostly unstated and hardly referred to in official loan approval statements, of course.) Insisting on its<br />

semi-independent status as an investment bank, the EIB also never officially agreed to restrict its transport<br />

lending activities in the region to the priority projects identified through the TINA and ISPA processes.<br />

Nevertheless, considerable cooperation and co-funding between ISPA and EIB transport projects occurs.<br />

For a detailed case study on these EIB investment rationales in comparison to other international<br />

development banks like the World Bank or the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, see<br />

(HELCOM 2000). For radial and up-to-date critiques of the overall EIB approach, and particularly its lack<br />

of transparency, see www.bankwatch.org


278<br />

Table 7.1<br />

Key Initiatives Related to EU Transport-Infrastructure Investments in CEE<br />

Initiative: HELSINKI TINA ISPA PHARE/LSIF<br />

CORRIDORS<br />

What is it? High-Level Political EU-funded EU Pre-Accession Until 1999: only<br />

Decision<br />

Identifying key EU-<br />

Transport<br />

Infrastructure Needs<br />

Grant Program for<br />

Transport &<br />

key EU Grant<br />

Program for<br />

CEE routes Assessment for CEE Environment CEEC<br />

Main<br />

Output<br />

Sponsored/<br />

Funded By<br />

Grants for Infrastructure,<br />

Institution-building,<br />

Twinning (‘00-)<br />

Decision-<br />

Makers<br />

Time-<br />

Frame<br />

Ten Multi-Modal<br />

Priority Transport<br />

Corridors in CEE<br />

Pan-European<br />

Transport Ministers<br />

& EU Commission<br />

(mainly DG TREN)<br />

Pan-European<br />

Transport Ministers<br />

Corridor Definition:<br />

until 1997<br />

Investment<br />

Coordination: 1997-<br />

Source: Own compilation<br />

Final report, TINA<br />

maps with backbone<br />

network &<br />

additional networks<br />

EU Commission<br />

(via PHARE)<br />

TINA Senior<br />

Officials Group:<br />

Member State &<br />

CEE representatives<br />

TINA process itself:<br />

1998-1999<br />

TINA time horizon:<br />

until 2015<br />

National CEE<br />

strategies with<br />

priority project list<br />

for EU funding<br />

EU Commission<br />

(DG REGIO)<br />

CEE Transport<br />

Ministries &<br />

EU Commission<br />

National Plans:<br />

2000<br />

Grant Funds:<br />

2000-2006<br />

EU Commission<br />

(misc. DGs)<br />

CEE Transport<br />

Ministries &<br />

EU Commission<br />

In operation<br />

(with different<br />

foci) since 1989<br />

7.3 From the E-Routes to the Pan-European Transport Corridors<br />

Before the transition, the main forum for cooperation between Eastern and<br />

Western European countries was the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe<br />

(UNECE). UNECE fostered international agreements for international road, rail and<br />

combined transport routes (the AGR, AGC, and AGCT, respectively) and initiated work<br />

programs on Trans-European Motorways (TEM) and Railways (TER), resulting in the socalled<br />

“E” routes scheme. 8<br />

However, while there was limited coordination on route<br />

8 Note that this work on the UNECE’s Trans-European Railway Lines (TER) and the Trans-European<br />

North-South Motorway Network (TEM) continues as a parallel effort to EU-CEE initiatives until this day.<br />

For additional information as well as updated maps of the TER and TEM networks see<br />

http://www.unece.org/trans/main/ter/termap.html and http://www.unece.org/trans/main/tem/temmap.html.


279<br />

selection, there was no actual cooperation on international planning or joint financing of<br />

priority investments.<br />

European Transport Ministers from both EU and Central Eastern European<br />

countries met for the first post-transition, Pan-European Ministers of Transport<br />

Conference in Prague in 1991. After that, the TEN process was immediately included in<br />

the Maastricht Treaty. Article 129c of the Treaty stipulates that<br />

the Community shall establish a series of guidelines covering the objectives, priorities<br />

and broad lines of measures envisaged in the sphere of trans-European networks; these<br />

guidelines shall identify projects of common interest.<br />

In the following years, the European Union’s TEN program emerged as an<br />

increasing focus of the EU’s “eastern thrust” (Ross 1998:187) and reflection of the EU’s<br />

pre-accession strategy. At the first Pan-European Transport Conference, the Dutch<br />

Ministry suggested that representatives focus on developing a map of transport priority<br />

corridors connecting the European Union to its eastern and southern neighbors. The<br />

concept was endorsed again at the June 1993 Transport Ministers’ summit in<br />

Copenhagen. The first set of nine international priority corridors was subsequently<br />

adopted at the Pan-European Transport Conference in Crete in 1995. Although most of<br />

the routes selected for the TENs were originally part of the UNECE E-routes, the<br />

dramatic shifts apparent in East-West travel patterns had already required some changes<br />

and additions to these older route selections. One corridor was added as late as June<br />

1997 during the Pan-European conference in Helsinki, completing what is now<br />

commonly referred to as the Helsinki Corridors. In addition, the conference identified<br />

several larger transport areas around the Barents, the Caspian, the Adriatic and the


280<br />

Mediterranean Seas. Figure 7.1 shows the map of the Pan-European Transport Network<br />

at the time of the Helsinki Summit.<br />

Figure 7.1 The Pan-European Transport Network with the 10 Helsinki Corridors<br />

Source: European Commission<br />

Arguing from a purely efficiency-oriented point of view, one would expect that<br />

the major criterion for the selection of the corridors would have been traffic flows. This<br />

was not the case, however. There is confusion even among DG TREN staff as to how<br />

exactly the corridors were decided upon. When asked to explain the history of the<br />

selection process, one expert said that he himself was told that there were several experts<br />

who gave input at various stages of the process, but that the original routes were<br />

researched by a desk officer at the Commission, who had based his selections mainly on<br />

library research in Brussels. Other anecdotal evidence of participants at the Pan-


281<br />

European ministerial meeting provides an even simpler, earlier explanation: during the<br />

first transport ministers meeting in Prague, one of the Western European ministers<br />

apparently had a sheet with brightly colored corridors on a map of Europe (supposedly<br />

more intended for personal purposes than for official presentation), and this eye-catching<br />

map subsequently became the basis of the corridor concept. Another interesting point is<br />

that the corridor concept was close to the kind of master planning approach that the<br />

representatives from the former Communist countries were used to. As a result, many of<br />

them seem to have been sympathetic to the concept despite the fact that the proposed<br />

corridors did not always express their national priorities, and the various color lines<br />

became the basis for political negotiations at the ministerial level.<br />

Part of the reason that the Helsinki Corridors did not have their basis in detailed<br />

traffic forecasts was that reliable pan-European traffic estimates for East-West flows<br />

simply did not exist at the time (also see below). The more important explanation is that<br />

the corridors were decided upon at a level of decision-making where geopolitics and<br />

national representational interests are simply more important than traffic counts.<br />

Commission staff pointed out, for example, that the Polish delegates did not include a<br />

main link from <strong>Berlin</strong> to Gdansk in the network – presumably largely for historical<br />

reasons. (Overall, however, the Polish government predominantly emphasized northsouth<br />

connections, less so east-west ones.)<br />

Since the corridors had to be determined by what would be politically acceptable<br />

to all stakeholders, the various selected routes were hardly of equal importance with<br />

regard to real existing Trans-European trade and transport flows. For political reasons,<br />

each capital city had to be included in at least one of the corridors. Although they were


282<br />

given equal weight on the resulting map, in reality the section of corridor II linking <strong>Berlin</strong><br />

and Warsaw was obviously of much greater importance for Pan-European trade and<br />

traffic flows than the stretch of corridor VII linking Durres to Tirana, for example. In<br />

fact, numerous experts confirmed that this latter corridor was added for purely political<br />

reasons.<br />

There was some competition between ECMT, UNECE and the European<br />

Commission over the corridor process at the Pan-European Transport conference in<br />

Crete, where the routes emerged more clearly. In the end, the Helsinki corridors still<br />

remain very close to the so-called E- routes which were developed by UNECE. Work on<br />

the Helsinki corridors continues until this day, mainly though what has become known as<br />

the Pan-European partnership. After 1997, separate Memoranda of Understanding<br />

(MOU) for the different corridors were concluded among the participating countries.<br />

These MOUs were voluntary commitments and recommended, among other things, the<br />

establishment of different steering committees for the various corridors. Since these<br />

MOUs, which can be considered administrative rather than governmental decisions, thus<br />

had no legal binding character, large differences in the efficiency of these cooperative<br />

efforts became obvious. 9<br />

Secretariats were particularly quickly established for Corridors<br />

I and IV. Work on the Via Baltica corridor is especially advanced.<br />

In early 2000, the TINA Office 10 prepared a status report on the Pan-European<br />

Corridors and Transport Areas which estimated the total lengths of the corridors at<br />

9 Until violent conflict was halted in the Balkans, MOUs could also not be signed for the entire lengths of<br />

the corridors 6, 7, 8, and 10 since all these corridors cross the territory of the Former Yugoslavia. On<br />

February 27, 2002 the MOU for the Danube corridor (VII) was signed in Brussels, leaving only the MOU<br />

for Corridor VIII to Albania to be completed (<br />

10 The TINA Secretariat was never officially linked to the European Commission. In fact, the TINA office<br />

was founded in February 1997 under the name “Wiener Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment<br />

Bürobetriebsges.m.b.H.” (WTB for short) and it is still a limited company under Austrian law. In the fall of


283<br />

25,310 km for the rail sector and 22,930 for the road sector. The costs were estimated at<br />

€ 32.6 and 39.6 billion until 2015, respectively, i.e. a total of € 72.9 billion, but the<br />

numbers are somewhat disputable. More importantly, the status report revealed once<br />

again that many of the so-called corridors hardly deserved their name, since many of<br />

them branch out into several routes that are sometimes hundreds of kilometers apart. Rail<br />

and road corridors are also often running along very different routes. Taking the example<br />

of Corridor IV running from Germany to Romania, Turkey and Greece, figures 7.2 and<br />

7.3 vividly illustrate the emerging network character of the corridors. Of course, the<br />

inclusion of more and more branches is largely a reflection of candidate states’ efforts to<br />

also include secondary and tertiary links between major cities. Note that in the case of<br />

Corridor IV, instead of defining one main corridor route linking Vienna, Bratislava and<br />

Budapest, several closely parallel - and therefore competing - rail lines are included in the<br />

corridor alignments.<br />

2001, TINA VIENNA became directly affiliated to the City of Vienna, continuing the previous work of the<br />

TINA Secretariat at a national level, while at the same time continuing to work as a consulting office. The<br />

current TINA website (http://www.tinavienna.at/buero.htm) explains its continued raison d’être as follows:<br />

The purpose of the foundation of this company was the implementation of the PHARE project<br />

"Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment" (TINA)-process in Central and Eastern Europe as a<br />

technical support body, named the "TINA Secretariat". To carry out the work, TINA VIENNA has,<br />

based on the excellent contacts within the Vienna Cities Administration [sic], established a wide<br />

network of contacts in the member states and in all CEECs, including Ministries, Universities and<br />

individual experts. One of the main strength [sic] of TINA VIENNA is the expertise in international<br />

strategic transport planning in Central and Eastern Europe.<br />

All projects, [sic] which TINA VIENNA has undertaken were financed by international financing<br />

institutes such as the EIB, EU-PHARE and TACIS.<br />

Nevertheless, copyrights for the TINA maps are always credited to the European Commission. Note that<br />

TINA VIENNA is currently also undertaking a Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment for Malta.


284<br />

Figure 7.2 Pan-European Transport Corridor IV – Road Sector<br />

Source: CEC and TINA (2000d)<br />

Figure 7.3 Pan-European Transport Corridor IV – Rail Sector<br />

Source: CEC and TINA (2000d)


285<br />

7.4 The Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment (TINA) for CEE<br />

7.4.1 From Politically-Defined Corridors to an Assessed Network?<br />

In order to put the politicized process of corridors prioritization on an ostensibly<br />

more scientific and more objective footing, the European Commission, in cooperation<br />

with the candidate states, and with financial assistance from the EU Phare Program and<br />

the City of Vienna, launched the “Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment” process.<br />

Even the European Commission itself readily admitted that the original Helsinki<br />

Corridors largely reflected EU strategic interests. Stakeholders agreed that a larger needs<br />

assessment for the candidate countries was necessary. The first official mention of a<br />

Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment (TINA) for the CEE candidate countries<br />

process was made at the first structured dialogue between the European Union Transport<br />

Council (of Ministers) and the relevant transport ministers of the candidate countries in<br />

1995. At the time, the main goal was an identification of the transport-sector investments<br />

required to bring transport infrastructures in CEE countries up to EU standards and to<br />

ensure adequate linkage between CEE and EU infrastructures. More importantly for the<br />

candidate countries, they realized that if the Helsinki Corridors were to become the main<br />

basis for identifying infrastructure projects that were of “common interest,” many of their<br />

national priority projects might not be eligible for funding within the EU’s emerging preaccession<br />

grant framework.<br />

The TINA process therefore had two underlying motivations which were often<br />

incongruent with each other: on one hand, TINA was to present a retroactive, supposedly<br />

de-politicized justification for the already selected priority routes by presenting data on<br />

future traffic flows and “bottlenecks”. On the other hand, TINA was also supposed to


286<br />

give CEE countries a second chance to retrofit the selections that had already been agreed<br />

upon at the ministerial level in light of additional national interests and newly emerging<br />

developments in terms of actual traffic flows in the region. The resulting TINA Final<br />

Report is thus a remarkable document that deserves some detailed attention.<br />

The preamble of the TINA report reiterates key EU interests in the region, noting<br />

that “the elements of the European Transport infrastructure network in the [Central<br />

European] region are vital to competitiveness, economic growth and employment<br />

throughout Europe, and in the European Union in particular” (TINA 1999:11). When<br />

pledging consistency with the “principle of sustainable mobility,” the report defines this<br />

principle as “bringing together the economic and social goals of efficiency, safety and<br />

minimalisation of environmental damage.” Multimodality is identified as a core aim.<br />

The TINA process is then divided into two main stages: first, an initial, cost-conscious<br />

definition of the network and second, the identification of investment measures which<br />

would the network “up to a desired quality level.” Built into the report was the typical,<br />

yet disputable assumption that forecasting present trends into the future alone presents a<br />

necessary justification for infrastructure expansion. As the report notes (p. 14):<br />

?? The network should be in line with the criteria laid down in the EU Guidelines for the<br />

Development of the TENs…<br />

?? The technical standards of the future infrastructure should ensure consistency<br />

between the capacity of network components and their expected traffic.…<br />

?? The time horizon for the achievement should be 2015.<br />

?? The cost of the network … should not exceed 1.5.% of each country’s annual GDP<br />

over the period up to 2015. (my emphasis)<br />

The most stunning fact with regard to the defined network, however, is that the<br />

vast majority of the so-called “needs assessment” consists of a rather blatant continuation


287<br />

of the politically defined corridor approach taken at the Pan-European Transport<br />

conferences. As the TINA report clearly states (p.14 and p.25):<br />

The [TINA] backbone network … was defined by the Commission, so as to be identical<br />

with the links and nodes of the ten multi-modal Pan-European Transport Corridors on<br />

the territory of the TINA countries. The routing of the Crete/Helsinki corridors was<br />

provided by the TINA Secretariat, using relevant information from the Steering<br />

Committee or other working groups of the Crete/Helsinki Corridors, and by consulting<br />

the UN TEM and TER offices, etc. It was understood that all parties concerned<br />

agreed on the need for the Corridors so that further economic or financial<br />

justifications were not required.<br />

(My emphasis).<br />

Rather different criteria were set for the potential additional network components,<br />

however. Here, proposals needed to be “accompanied by sufficient information on its<br />

economic viability” (p. 14). Regardless of the existence of these new criteria, however,<br />

early lobbying of Estonia and Latvia, already resulted in the addition of one new major<br />

East-West link from Corridor I towards corridor IX in each country. Additionally, the<br />

criteria concerned the continuity of the links at the borders between TINA countries, at<br />

the borders with NIS and EU countries, as well as the general consistency of the network<br />

structures. The latter was explicitly understood to mean that there should be “no missing<br />

links in the total TEN-TINA network” (p.25). Figures 7.4 and 7.5 show the final<br />

proposed road and rail networks for the candidate countries as presented in the TINA<br />

final report in October 1999. Figures 7.6 and 7.7 provide a more detailed overview of the<br />

selected road and rail infrastructures for Poland and Hungary.


288<br />

Figure 7.4 TINA Road Network<br />

Source: TINA Final Report


289<br />

Figure 7.5 TINA Rail Network<br />

Source: TINA Final Report


290<br />

Figure 7.6 TINA Network Poland<br />

Source: TINA Final Report


291<br />

Figure 7.7 TINA Network Hungary<br />

Source: TINA Final Report


292<br />

The total needs listed under TINA are enormous, and meeting the investment<br />

schedule under the 2010 time horizon would involve spending more than 1.5% of the<br />

country's GDP in some of the candidate countries. Senior Commission representatives<br />

consider this a realistic and doable investment plan. They also pride themselves in<br />

having lowered overly elevated infrastructure building cost estimates on the part of the<br />

candidate countries sometimes by a factor of 3. 11<br />

In the end, however, the high-profile<br />

TINA exercise did not achieve full consensus in arriving at routing and infrastructure<br />

investment decisions. The following sections investigate both the network alignment and<br />

the needs assessment decision-making processes in more detail.<br />

7.4.2 Continued Politicking: European versus National Interests<br />

The final TINA maps are especially inconsistent with regard to the criterion of<br />

linking up all TINA and TEN routes, largely for political reasons. A close inspection of<br />

figures 7.4 and 7.5 reveals that four of the additional TINA road components as well as<br />

one of the new rail lines on the Czech side have no continuation on the German and/or<br />

Austrian sides (also see TINA 1999:27-28). Also, there was rather harsh criticism from<br />

many of the CEE governmental representatives with regard to several of the elements<br />

included in the final TINA report. The following comments, extracted from a series of<br />

governmental statements included as Annex XIV to the Final TINA report, provide<br />

telling insights as to some of the persistent disagreements apparent throughout the<br />

process:<br />

11 In the case of Poland, Commission-hired consultants supposedly found cost estimates for a variety of<br />

road infrastructure schemes to be lower than Polish supplied data by a factor of 2.


293<br />

It is our opinion that the TINA Secretariat should give some advice in accepting or not<br />

accepting the objections of the Romanian government towards construction of a<br />

second combined (rail and road) bridge across the river Danube at Vidin – Calafat. …<br />

[Also] we are extremely surprised that after all discussions, sent data and the<br />

succeeding decisions on this page of the Final TINA Report Haskovo – Makaza is still<br />

treated as a branch with no continuation on the Greek side. We absolutely object to<br />

this reappearing problem to be included in the Final Report.<br />

Petko Tabakov, Deputy Minister of Transport, Bulgaria<br />

What will be the role of the Steering Committee of the Pan-European Transport<br />

Corridors in comparison to the TINA follow-up?<br />

Juhani Tervala, Finish Representative of the TINA Senior Officials Group<br />

You refer to a “common method for socio-economic project assessment, as endorsed<br />

in September 1999 by the Group.” To our knowledge, the Group has not endorsed<br />

anything, and up to now, we have not seen such a method that would be acceptable<br />

and workable. 12<br />

G. Chatelus, French Ministry of Transport<br />

Hungary feels that the realization of the Szekesfehevar – Bogond – Pustzaszabolcs –<br />

Adony – Cegled railways alignment is not realistic until 2015 as indicated.<br />

András Hardy, Director General, Hungarian Ministry of Transport<br />

Who are the “respective authors”? Why [do] TINA countries have no access to the<br />

database? … At present there are no three (3) lane roads and in future there will not be<br />

[any] three (3) lane roads in Poland because the construction of such roads is not<br />

permitted by the Polish Law.<br />

Adam Grodzicki, Polish Ministry of Transport (re-iterating/re-including comments by<br />

the Polish Steering Committee representative during the final meeting in Triest in<br />

1999)<br />

Given these continued misunderstandings and disagreements, the status of TINA<br />

as the guiding tool for EU investment in CEE transport infrastructure was problematic –<br />

and TINA always remained a somewhat disputed document even within the Commission<br />

itself.<br />

12 The above text represents an unofficial English translation provided the TINA secretariat. The original<br />

French text read as follows: “Le rapport fait reference à une “common method for socio-economic project<br />

assessment, as endorsed in September 1999 by the Group”. A notre connaissance, le Groupe n’a pas adopté<br />

quoi que ce soit, et jusqu’à présent nous n’avons pas eu connaissance d’une telle méthode qui serait<br />

acceptable et fonctionnelle.“


294<br />

7.4.3 Defining the Desired Future: EU Status Quo Defines CEE Needs<br />

Apart from political problems, the TINA initiative was also fraught with serious<br />

methodological difficulties. With a time horizon of over 15 years, the estimations on<br />

future expected traffic flows were necessarily highly speculative. Despite the fact that a<br />

trilateral expert team from three very respected research institutions (NEA in the<br />

Netherlands, IWW in Germany and INRETS in France) carried out the traffic forecasting,<br />

traffic forecasts across international borders were still regarded as very unreliable by<br />

several experts. To make matters worse, some of the national experts also strongly<br />

doubted the accuracy of national level data produced by the international experts. The<br />

Latvian Ministry of Transport was most emphatic in its official disapproval of the<br />

consultant’s forecasting results (TINA 1999:Annex XIV):<br />

MoT of Latvia can not [sic] agree and asks to disregard the study carried out by NEA<br />

regarding forecasts for Latvia. For whatever reasons the results of the study<br />

addressing rail and partially also road traffic forecasts for 2015 are out of any common<br />

sense. They are in most cases completely different from what Latvian authorities as<br />

well as international consultants have forecasted.<br />

Vigo Legzidins, Director of Investment and Transit Policy Department, Ministry of<br />

Transport, Latvia.<br />

This assessment is especially damning in light of the fact that these harshly<br />

criticized future demand forecasts calculated by the NEA, IWW and INRETS consultants<br />

provided the very basis for the “assessed needs” of the TINA exercise. As the final<br />

report itself stressed:<br />

In the TINA process, the future demand should define the needs of the infrastructure<br />

to be constructed. This future demand was investigated for all modes, from the results<br />

of a relevant PHARE Study [done by COWI Consult]. This Final Report bases some<br />

conclusions on the network design on the results of this Study, using a traffic scenario<br />

with the maximum forecasted traffic per section.


295<br />

In Poland, internationally renowned senior-level traffic experts were equally critical of<br />

the forecasts done by the Western consultants. Some of the NEA forecast models<br />

supposedly predicted off-the-chart numbers such as train densities of over 200 trains per<br />

day on the <strong>Berlin</strong> – Warsaw corridor. (Currently, there are about 4 international trains a<br />

day.) As with most modeling exercises, small discrepancies in the used data can lead to<br />

unrealistic results that need to be backed up by knowledgeable (national-level) expertise.<br />

This was apparently not the case in this exercise.<br />

At least as important as the questionability of the obtained results due to internal<br />

miscalculations and incorrect parameter inputs is the fact that the overall extrapolation<br />

method used, while seemingly rational within an overall eco-modernist discursive<br />

framework that stresses growth, was based on the very same assumed relationship<br />

between transport and growth that the EU’s own Sustainable Development Strategy<br />

criticizes and seeks to remedy in the future. In other words: contrary to their own SDS,<br />

which states that the EU will “decouple transport growth significantly from growth in<br />

Gross Domestic Product” (Commission of the European Communities 2001a:12) in order<br />

to “improve the transport system and land-use management,” the EU’s future needs<br />

assessment for transport infrastructures in the candidate countries was based on a<br />

traditional eco-modernist calculation that assumed a parallel development of GDP and<br />

transport growth:<br />

The basic economic data about the eleven countries for the base year 1995 were<br />

provided by the NEA Study on “Traffic forecast on the 10 Pan-European Corridors of<br />

Helsinki.” … In 1995, the eleven candidate countries had a population of 106 million<br />

people …[and] they had an average per capita gross domestic product of about €<br />

2,300 … These data constitute a starting point for extrapolations for the future. The<br />

most important assumptions relate to economic growth in the countries. … Following<br />

these assumptions [about a moderate growth scenario] the total produced GDP in the<br />

candidate countries in the period 1998 to 2015 is about € 7.330 billion. …


296<br />

Extrapolations to the future years are made under the assumption that growth rates<br />

gradually converge with average growth rates in the Union. (p.21-22, my emphasis.)<br />

To boot, apart from providing the basis for the assumed transport future, these<br />

extrapolations of current economic growth rates also formed the basis for calculating the<br />

total of the desired transport infrastructure investments in CEE. The proposed solution is<br />

an interesting example of the type of reverse-logic, growth-oriented rationalizations often<br />

used to justify large-scale transport infrastructure investments. Choosing to ignore stateof-the-art<br />

academic debates over the changing relationship between infrastructure<br />

investments and growth (discussed in the initial chapter of this study), the TINA group<br />

instead reverted to a normative approach that simply determined that a set percentage of<br />

the GDP constituted a desirable level of infrastructure investment. The recurring use of<br />

conditional phrasing is indicative:<br />

In the past, the Group has discussed how infrastructure investments should relate to<br />

the GDP. EU Member States invest between slightly under 1% and up to 2% of GDP<br />

in Union-relevant infrastructure. … The discussion also confirmed, however, that the<br />

acceding countries needed to do somewhat more. … The group agreed to accept, as an<br />

indicator for a realistic ceiling of planned infrastructure investments, that their cost<br />

should not on average exceed 1.5% of the GDP in the coming years. Assuming that<br />

transport ministers would like to achieve this level, this would give an infrastructure<br />

investment bracket for each country based on the different growth scenarios between<br />

now and 2015. (p.24, my emphasis).<br />

TINA thus assesses the desirable levels of future investment levels in the CEE<br />

candidate states by using (non-referenced) data on current GDP-investment ratios in the<br />

mature economies of the European Union. As a consequence, the desirable CEE future is<br />

assessed by using the EU’s status quo as its main input. In addition, this supposed status<br />

quo input is highly questionable given the wide range of investment ratios in Western<br />

Europe both between countries and over time. The EU’s own data show that in 1996, for


297<br />

example, the range was in fact between 0.5 and 1.4 percent of GDP, averaging 1.1<br />

percent (see figure below). 13<br />

Apart from its methodological questionability, such an<br />

approach is, of course, also questionable from a larger sustainability perspective,<br />

precisely because it is so fundamentally uncritical of the status quo - which is also why<br />

the TINA exercise is such a revealingly typical example of an eco-modernist<br />

rationalization process.<br />

Figure 7.8 EU Data on Transport Infrastructure Investment as Percentage of GDP<br />

Source: http://europa.eu.int/comm/energy_transport/etif/transport_general/infrastructure<br />

_investment.html, Last accessed 13 June, 2002<br />

13 Also note that up to 1994, these data, displayed on the EU DG TREN website, were produced by the<br />

European Centre for Infrastructure Studies (ECIS), a pro-infrastructure research center set up in the early<br />

1990s in the wake of the first TEN ‘missing links’ enthusiasm. The center closed under somewhat<br />

mysterious circumstances in 1996, including financial disagreements.


298<br />

7.4.4 Network Assessment & Priority Corridors: Contradictory Discourses<br />

When asked about the relationship between the work on the Helsinki priority<br />

corridors and the more inclusive TINA networks, Commission staff provided<br />

contradictory answers. Some still hold that the Helsinki corridors are simply the<br />

backbone, or first-order network of the larger TINA network, thus hinting at a<br />

continuation of a two-tier structure. This is also still mostly the position of the Regional<br />

Policy directorate, which administers the ISPA program. DG TREN officials, by<br />

contrast, prefer to point out that the notion of corridors is mostly “outdated,” and that one<br />

should instead only think in term of interoperable networks. This contradictory<br />

assessment is also reflected in the somewhat twisted, non-committal formulations<br />

regarding the eligibility of Helsinki corridors versus additional TINA network sections<br />

for future ISPA funding. On one hand, the TINA document repeatedly asserts the<br />

priority of (politically defined) backbone network over the additional components:<br />

The TINA process will eventually lead to the identification of viable investment<br />

projects, which will, in the future extended TEN-TR, be candidates for projects of<br />

common interest. In the context of pre-accession financing, the ISPA team will, on<br />

the basis of the TINA findings, perform a more detailed project analysis of all projects<br />

which will be considered for financing. (p.13)<br />

As a final result of the TINA process, the total network is proposed for<br />

implementation in the time horizon of 2015. However, the backbone network is seen<br />

as that part of the network, which should have a certain priority in its construction.<br />

(p.15., emphasis in the original.)<br />

While the Group has not established a list of priority projects, it recommends that, in<br />

principle, priority be given to financing the backbone network over other components<br />

of the network. (p.88)<br />

On the other hand, however, the TINA report also presents an interesting,<br />

additional list of criteria for the ultimate prioritization under ISPA (see p.17):


299<br />

The question of priorities is still open. The maturity of a project is an essential factor<br />

for its selection for European funding. Other main parameters that can influence the<br />

priority of a project are whether the projects contributes towards<br />

?? increase of capacity – elimination of bottlenecks;<br />

?? development of links toward not well-developed areas;<br />

?? development of links to the TENs;<br />

?? better functioning of the network – increase of its attractiveness;<br />

?? completion of an already started programme;<br />

?? lower operating costs;<br />

?? etc.<br />

This list is particularly interesting in light of future emerging justifications for<br />

individual projects under ISPA. The argument that projects should receive funding<br />

simply because they have already been started is certainly curious. Moreover, embedded<br />

in an overall modernization discourse emphasizing “missing links” and “bottlenecks” we<br />

suddenly also find elements of a “infrastructure-for-cohesion” discourse, namely via the<br />

reference of “links towards not well-developed areas.” In essence, this formulation<br />

leaves the door open for cohesion-type rural infrastructure projects that could not<br />

otherwise be justified via economic or financial assessment criteria. This is a particularly<br />

sensitive issue in the case of Hungary’s disputed M3 highway crosses rural territory in<br />

Eastern Hungary and ends at the Ukrainian border (also see Hook 1998a).<br />

A further remark about “bottlenecks” is in order as well. Although discourses<br />

related to “bottlenecks” were clearly the types of rhetorical tropes which the authors of<br />

the report welcomed to further highlight the urgency of their cause, it seems that it was<br />

very clear to everyone involved that the related maps in Annex IX of the report indicating<br />

“TINA Road and Rail Bottlenecks” for the year 2005, 2010 and 2015 would never hold<br />

up as accurate predictions of future CEE infrastructure capacity deficiencies. In any case,<br />

the TINA report itself makes little to no reference to these maps, thus already implicitly


300<br />

relegating them to the status of a visually impressive yet ultimately unrealistic GIS-aided<br />

desktop exercise.<br />

Clearly, the Commission was not ignorant of the important methodological<br />

problems related to assessing and prioritising transport infrastructure needs at the<br />

network level. Quite to the contrary, DG TREN staff had been working for quite some<br />

time with outside experts on the elaboration of a manual that would provide guidance on<br />

such strategic assessment matters. Here, we find surprisingly exact instructions as to how<br />

a Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment process that truly deserved the label<br />

“assessment” could and should have been organized (Commission of the European<br />

Communities 2000e:iv):<br />

An assessment of a transport infrastructure plan at network level should include the<br />

following components:<br />

· assessment of the existing multi-modal transport network and expected future<br />

changes using established environmental objectives and standards;<br />

· identification of alternative courses of action to improve the expected future<br />

situation, including transport infrastructure proposals;<br />

· forecasting the impacts of the alternatives on the environment.<br />

Modal alternatives at network level should be developed sufficiently to permit<br />

assessment of the plan as a whole. This implies that decisions about particular<br />

corridors within the network should be postponed until planning, assessment and<br />

decision-making at corridor level is undertaken.<br />

[Bold emphases in the original, italic emphases added].<br />

According to this logic, the actual procedure followed by the EU and the<br />

participating government of first selecting corridors and then attempted to retrofit the<br />

corridors into a larger network, clearly made no sense. Seen from a “rational” assessment<br />

perspective, there should have been no decisions made about particular corridors and<br />

their modes before an overall assessment was done. More importantly, modal<br />

alternatives and alternative routes would have had to be provided in order to enable an


301<br />

actual choice considering future network development. This was not the case with the<br />

TINA exercise.<br />

7.5 The Environmental Scoping Exercise on the Warsaw – Budapest Corridor<br />

Many transport experts were aware of the above described deficiencies in the<br />

TINA process and favored alternative, less status-quo oriented transport infrastructure<br />

investment scenarios for Central Europe. A key focus of the critique was that a<br />

comprehensive environmental evaluation should have been undertaken of the overall<br />

network plans.<br />

International transport experts at universities and international<br />

organizations had long argued in favor of carrying out a so-called Strategic<br />

Environmental Assessment (SEA) on the TENs, on the TEN extensions and on the future<br />

Pan-European Transport Network as a whole. Strategic environmental assessment is a<br />

rapidly evolving area of professional practice. SEA can be defined as “a formalized,<br />

systematic and comprehensive process that evaluates the environmental impacts of PPPs<br />

[policies, plans and programs], considers alternatives, includes a written report on the<br />

findings of the evaluation and uses these findings in publicly accountable decision<br />

making” (Therivel, Wilson et al. 1992; Fischer 2002). Even the Commission’s Transport<br />

Directorate has nothing but praise for the method on its own website (Commission of the<br />

European Communities 2002a):<br />

Strategic environmental assessment (SEA) provides information about the<br />

environmental consequences of decisions about policies, plans and programmes. It is<br />

increasingly being applied to transport infrastructure plans. … SEA makes transport<br />

more sustainable. At the European Union level, its importance was recognised at the<br />

1998 meeting of heads of governments (the Cardiff Summit). The European Union<br />

strives to integrate environmental considerations into its own policy making and the


302<br />

European Commission has stated, in its 1992 White Paper on a Common Transport<br />

Policy, that it will apply SEA for infrastructure plans.<br />

The incessant calls for doing an SEA on Trans-European Networks were also the<br />

main reason why DG TREN developed the above quoted manual. So why did the EU not<br />

carry out any strategic assessments at the network level before defining corridors? The<br />

reasons for this are multiple, some of them clearly being of a methodological nature (no<br />

overall consensus on methodologies, data problems relating mostly to availability and<br />

inconsistency). Most importantly, however, there were two reasons: first of all, there was<br />

no political consensus that modal substitution was even an option along key corridors.<br />

Second, even the most sophisticated strategic assessments still need to measure their<br />

proposed infrastructure scenarios against different technical and environmental targets.<br />

There thus would have had to also be a political consensus on clear sustainable transport<br />

and mobility objectives.<br />

Nevertheless, by 1999, doing an SEA for the CEE TEN extension plan seemed all<br />

the more important since the chance to do a timely SEA for the TENs had missed. 14<br />

In<br />

particular, the 1999 ECMT/OECD workshop “SEA in the Transport Sector” called for<br />

the priority application of SEA for transport infrastructure development plans laid down<br />

in TINA recommendations (OECD/ECMT 1999:5-6).<br />

The European Union Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment (TINA) programme<br />

presents the best immediate opportunity to develop SEA experience in the region and<br />

more fundamentally raises a clear need for such an assessment. Ideally countries<br />

along pan-European transport corridors along which TINA projects have been<br />

nominated should co-operate to undertake joint SEAs. The results should help shape<br />

the eventual selection of projects for financial support from European Union and<br />

international finance institution funds and contribute to improving the design of the<br />

14 Richardson (2000) provides an in-depth analysis of the “SEA on the TENs”-debate. The account now<br />

has to be partially updated in light of recent developments, since there is now increasing consensus that<br />

strategic assessments should be carried out on all EU TEN infrastructure projects.


303<br />

projects and the overall development of the transport corridors. The recent Trans<br />

European Network transport corridor studies, co-funded by the European Commission,<br />

can provide methodological guidance.<br />

The Commission therefore organized an “Environmental Scoping” on the Multi-<br />

Modal Transport Corridor VI. from Warsaw to Budapest organized by the Regional<br />

Environmental Center (REC) in Szentendre, Hungary. This scooping exercise was a<br />

partial if limited response to the ECMT’s somewhat ambiguously formulated call. It can<br />

hardly be regarded as an acceptable shorthand version of a full strategic assessment of<br />

TINA, however. While the original aim was in fact to assess the environmental impacts<br />

of all the transport policies in the entire CEE region, i.e. do a full “SEA of the TINA<br />

network”, this ambitious aim was quickly scaled down. As the Italian SEA expert Olivia<br />

Bina (1999) already noted during the Warsaw SEA conference: “[it is] not feasible … to<br />

attempt to complete a full assessment of the impacts of the network at this large scale of<br />

analysis.” The compromise solution was to focus on one multi-modal corridor instead. It<br />

was believed that “a well chosen corridor would provide, if not representative, at least<br />

indicative evidence of the potential environmental problems faced by the rest of the<br />

region.” The general objectives of the Warsaw – Budapest corridor initial scooping were<br />

defined as follows (Regional Environmental Centre for CEE (REC) 2000:2):<br />

- To identify potential impacts of the proposed development of transport infrastructure<br />

in CEE on environmental commitments of CEE countries,<br />

- To suggest suitable tools for integration of environment and transport (with specific<br />

focus on potential application of SEA for international transport planning in CEE),<br />

- To suggest practical provisions for effective coordination of environmental and<br />

transport planning on CEE regional level [sic].<br />

However, the report also clearly acknowledged the impossibility of doing any real<br />

ex-ante evaluation, since the corridor was already a designated Pan-European corridor


304<br />

and as such part of the priority investment list of both national and international planning<br />

documents. The scoping therefore was to be carried out as an ad interim assessment,<br />

focusing on existing environmental and transport policy contexts. The final synthesis<br />

report of the exercise begins by noting that “the EU Accession Process is the main driver<br />

of change in Central and Eastern Europe” (REC 2000:1). The EU Accession process has<br />

indeed already fundamentally transformed not only the transport, but also the<br />

environmental policies in the CEE candidate countries. 15<br />

Several conclusions that emerged from the REC exercise are revealing. For<br />

example, the report notes that urban air pollution and loss of habitat are two major<br />

impacts directly related to rising traffic volumes, which are in turn related to higher<br />

incomes and accelerated trade between East and West. Much more importantly, the<br />

authors of the synthesis report come to the clear conclusion that “the Community support<br />

for the TEN [extensions in CEE] is drawing the limited national resources primarily<br />

towards construction of long distance infrastructure, primarily highways” (REC 2000:9,<br />

my emphasis). Moreover, REC researchers found that now that the backbone network of<br />

the Trans-European network extensions had been determined in the form of the Helsinki<br />

corridors, CEE in-country representatives frequently (and often purposely) misinterpreted<br />

the TEN-extensions and the entire TINA exercise as an agreed and consultative<br />

international agreement awaiting implementation at the national level. The argument was<br />

often made in conjunction with the myth that the TINA backbone network was something<br />

that would largely be funded by the EU (i.e. ISPA) and the IFIs. Consequently, anyone<br />

opposing the content and priority networks contained in TINA appeared to be<br />

15 Most CEE countries have by now adopted National Environmental Policies, National Environmental<br />

Action Programs, and National Transport Policies that take into account EU requirements and regulations,<br />

as well as strategic objectives.


305<br />

jeopardizing international funding assistance for their countries (Dusik 2000). 16<br />

And<br />

since, this line of argument continued, EU and IFI co-financing is mostly available for<br />

backbone infrastructures, national priorities should consequently be redirected in the<br />

same direction, regardless of actual independently assessed needs. The research carried<br />

out as part of this environmental scooping exercise thus confirmed suspicions that TINA<br />

effectively overrode national transport policies in the sense that national-level priorities<br />

were changed according to what the TINA final report stated (Fleischer 2000).<br />

Finally, the various scoping reports also pointed to the fact that since ISPA is<br />

modeled on the Cohesion Fund, EU transport sector grant assistance currently cannot be<br />

given for much needed urban public transit improvements, thereby further exacerbating<br />

detrimental disinvestments trends. This likely over-prioritization of large-scale EU-CEE<br />

road connections to the detriment of other key national infrastructure needs may be in<br />

part be a tragedy of unintended consequences. It does not make it any less problematic,<br />

however.<br />

7.6 Epilogue: The Proposed Hungarian Amendments to the TINA Network<br />

Not all governments were prepared to accept the network proposed in the TINA<br />

final report as the last word on the issue. As late as early 2001, i.e. well after the<br />

completion of the ISPA national strategy documents, the Hungarian government<br />

proposed several specific amendments to the TINA rail and road networks, as well as two<br />

additional TINA airports in Hungary. As justifications for these amendments, the<br />

16<br />

Another key issue from a procedural perspective is that TINA was still largely a “closed room<br />

assessment” in the sense that the process only involved the transport ministries, and excluded decisionmakers<br />

from the Ministries of Finance, Environment or Regional Development as well as civil society<br />

stakeholders.


306<br />

Hungarians list “general economic and social development,” “advanced integration<br />

negotiations,” “the political changes in Yugoslavia,” and “the Hungarian ISPA and<br />

several sector strategies” (KöViM 2001). The proposed amendments are largely<br />

congruent with those Hungarian national ISPA transport priorities that would not<br />

otherwise be justifiable as TINA priorities. In particular, they concern road connections<br />

from Rábafüzes to Biharkeresztes (with a new bridge over the Danube) and between<br />

Mosonmagyaróvár and Nagykanizsa, a rail link between Sopron and Szombathely and<br />

two regional airports at Debrecen and Sárméllek. (For details on the Hungarian ISPA<br />

projects, see chapter 8.)<br />

Note that these proposals must be seen as additional even to the Hungarian<br />

government’s own investment priorities, particularly with regard to the road sector.<br />

Figure 7.11 provides an overview map of Hungary’s planned motorway and expressway<br />

investments from 2000 to 2010. The map clearly demonstrates that Hungarian road<br />

sector national priorities, at least in their 1999 accepted version, are fully congruent with<br />

the TINA backbone network (compare figure 7.11 with figures 7.9 and 7.10).


307<br />

Figure 7.9 Proposed Hungarian TINA Road, Port and Airport Amendments<br />

Source: Modified from KÖVIM (2001)<br />

Figure 7.10 Proposed Hungarian TINA Rail Amendments<br />

Source: Modified from KÖVIM (2001)


308<br />

Figure 7.11 Hungary’s Motorway Investment Plan 2000-2010<br />

Source: Lukács (2001)<br />

7.7 Conclusions and Consequences<br />

On a positive note, even if the true reality of transport corridor assessment in the<br />

“New Europe” is likely to continue to be dominated by political opportunism and geostrategic<br />

thinking, significant strides in developing better environmental, social and<br />

financial assessment methodologies for large-scale infrastructure investments have been<br />

made. Unfortunately, SEAs and EIAs are not always carefully and extensively enough<br />

applied, especially when it comes to EU-funded transport projects in CEE. Such is also<br />

the conclusion of the European Environmental Agency which notes in its latest TERM<br />

report (European Environment Agency (EEA) 2001:48) that “the practice of strategic<br />

environmental assessment is growing, but links with actual decision-making are weak.”


309<br />

In the case of the TINA exercise, the Realrationalität of the process incorporated<br />

the foundational premise and core belief of growth-led (ecological) modernization into its<br />

analysis in such a way that its conclusions appear as “objective” assessments and “truths”<br />

rather than the rationality-as-rationalization exercise that it was. Almost by definition,<br />

the TINA process puts a disproportionate emphasis on international links, i.e.<br />

international travel. The problem here is that, in fact, especially with regard to passenger<br />

traffic volumes, long distance international travel still only accounts for a tiny fraction of<br />

the total traffic volumes in Central Europe. The vast majority of passenger transport<br />

needs are either within or between major urban centers. The situation is similar for goods<br />

transport. While recent Eurostat figures show that road freight transport is in fact more<br />

“international” in CEE than in the EU, this is mainly due to the smaller size of CEE<br />

countries. (A truck traveling the 600 km from Munich to <strong>Berlin</strong> is still considered<br />

“national travel,” whereas a truck traveling the 340 km from Prague to <strong>Berlin</strong> is<br />

considered “international travel.”) Figure 7.12 shows that the share of international<br />

traffic is about twice as large in CEE countries as in the EU. A greater emphasis on<br />

upgrading east-west transport links is thus indeed justified. Nevertheless, over half of all<br />

traffic in CEE countries is national in scope, and, as figure 7.13 shows almost 80% of this<br />

traffic is over distances of less than 50km. The comparative figure for EU countries is<br />

60%. Also, 17% of all national EU traffic travels very long distances (over 150km),<br />

whereas this is only the case for 8% of national CEE traffic. This means that from the<br />

perspective of the respective countries, investment in regional level transport<br />

infrastructure should have at least an equally high priority as international infrastructure.


310<br />

Figure 7.12 Share of international road freight traffic measured in ton-kilometers<br />

%<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

international national cross-trade<br />

EU<br />

CEE<br />

Data Source: Eurostat (1999)<br />

Figure 7.13 National Goods by Distance Traveled in the EU and CEE<br />

100%<br />

80%<br />

60%<br />

40%<br />

20%<br />

0%<br />

0-49km 50-150km over 150km<br />

EU<br />

CEE<br />

Data Source: Eurostat (1999)<br />

The now foreseen concentration of EU grant funds on only select EU-accession<br />

oriented international routes will therefore not meet those countries’ general<br />

infrastructure needs. This is an argument which is particularly relevant for rail<br />

infrastructures. As an important CEPS Working Party report (Centre For European<br />

Policy Studies - CEPS 1999) notes:<br />

TINA's stress on trans-national networks is an important step towards extending the<br />

narrow national planning horizons which are a major obstacle to heavy rail's<br />

development. However, it also transfers the Union’s concept of subsidiarity into a<br />

setting which requires a much broader view of transport needs.


311<br />

With regard to the TINA exercise, we have to somewhat reconsider our<br />

“Decisional Power” proposition which assumed a predominance of multi-national and<br />

national transport interests. The bias towards international, long distance infrastructures<br />

which the Helsinki Corridor and the TINA processes aim to justify is certainly in the<br />

interest of the kinds of multinational corporations active in the European Round Table of<br />

Industrialists (ERT). However, the overall process of drawing up the CEE Transport<br />

Network plans displays quite a different dynamic from the type of targeted “Missing<br />

Links” industry pet project lobbing that went on during the development of the TEN<br />

priority projects. Participants confirm that both the Helsinki Corridors and the TINA<br />

processes were driven by the Commission and national governments, without any real<br />

influence of either private sector interests or civil society. Much of this has to do with the<br />

fact that during the time of their development, the Helsinki Corridors bore no concrete<br />

promise of a special EU grant fund budget line looming in the background. There was<br />

thus more room for national government-dominated politicking. This politicking,<br />

however, was limited to debates over the inclusion of additional transport infrastructure<br />

links of inter-urban and supra-regional importance. Whether or not even these additional,<br />

secondary links in fact represent the true priority interests of these countries from a<br />

sustainable transport development perspective is yet a different question – one that will<br />

be answered affirmatively by highway and high-speed rail-oriented modernizationists and<br />

negatively by political economy or renunciation-oriented sustainability advocates, and in<br />

fact by almost everyone else. In any case, even very mainstream transport experts (e.g.<br />

World Bank and EBRD senior transport specialists) emphasize that given the<br />

maintenance backlog and dire financial situation of CEE countries, the expensive new


312<br />

construction of additional infrastructures should not take priority over the much needed<br />

maintenance of already existing roads and rail lines of regional importance.<br />

In sum, while from the point of view of the Commission, the TINA process was<br />

an attempt to politically and scientifically justify their foreseen emphasis on international<br />

corridors with regard to future ISPA grant funding, from the point of view of the<br />

participating CEE governments, TINA was their best chance to “amend” the Helsinki<br />

Corridor commitments and to make a case for the inclusion of additional national priority<br />

networks. As we will see in our analysis of the Polish and Hungarian ISPA transport<br />

grants, the backbone corridor prioritization proved to be a hard one to undo.


313<br />

Printed on Sunday, November 17, 2002<br />

CHAPTER 8<br />

EU Pre-Accession Transport Infrastructure<br />

Funding for Poland and Hungary<br />

8.1 Introduction..................................................................................................... 314<br />

8.2 EU and IFI Transport Sector Assistance to Poland and Hungary Pre-ISPA .. 318<br />

8.2.1 IFI Transport Sector Loans to Poland and Hungary (1990-2001) .......... 318<br />

8.2.2 EU Transport Sector Grants Pre-ISPA: Phare and LISF (1990-1999) ... 321<br />

8.3 A Precursor to Cohesion Funding? Overview of ISPA Priorities................... 324<br />

8.4 EU ISPA Transport Funding for Poland......................................................... 330<br />

8.4.1 The National Context: Polish Transport Policy (Post-Transition).......... 330<br />

8.4.2 The Polish ISPA Transport Strategy and Its Priorities ........................... 336<br />

8.4.3 Preliminary Conclusions: EU ISPA Grants for Poland (2000-2001) ..... 340<br />

8.5 EU ISPA Transport Funding for Hungary...................................................... 342<br />

8.5.1 The National Context: Hungarian Transport Policy (Post- Transition).. 342<br />

8.5.2 The Hungarian ISPA Transport Strategies and their Priorities............... 352<br />

8.5.3 Preliminary Conclusions: EU ISPA grants for Hungary (2000-2001) ... 355<br />

8.6 Concluding Remarks on the EU’s ISPA Transport Program.......................... 357


314<br />

8.1 Introduction<br />

This chapter will investigate EU pre-accession grant-making for transport<br />

infrastructure investments under the EU ISPA (Instrument for Structural Policies for Pre-<br />

Accession) program. I review the first two years of ISPA transport-sector funding in two<br />

of the most advanced candidate countries, Poland and Hungary. Until now, I<br />

concentrated on the strategic aspects of EU transport decision-making, i.e. on transport<br />

policies, plans and programs. Chapter 7 showed that the EU’s emphasis on creating an<br />

international priority backbone network connecting the candidate countries to Western<br />

Europe was the driving factor in the elaboration of the TINA network maps. TINA was a<br />

declared effort to make the EU’s Pan-European priorities congruent with the accessions<br />

countries’ own national infrastructure priorities. ISPA, by contrast, supports actual<br />

infrastructure projects in the fields of transport and environment. 1<br />

Hence, ISPA is clearly<br />

the significant point of contact where EU transport sector decision-making and funding<br />

rationalities meet national CEE government rationalities. I thus move away even further<br />

from a discourse-focused approach towards a more reality-focused evaluation.<br />

Of course, I will not attempt to evaluate the consequences of all international,<br />

regional and local traffic and land use impacts of each individual transport project that<br />

has received ISPA funding. Not only is this much beyond the scope of this study, it is<br />

also still impossible at the present time. The European Union only officially launched its<br />

ISPA program in April 2000. Since almost none of the infrastructures slanted for funding<br />

in 2000 and 2001 have been completed, ISPA projects cannot yet undergo any ex-post<br />

1 There are currently the other two grant programs assisting the ten CEE candidate countries: Phare and<br />

Sapard. Sapard deals with the modernization of agriculture and rural development and does not concern us<br />

here. For details on the Phare program, see section 8.2.2 below.


315<br />

evaluation. 2<br />

What is possible, however, is an evaluation of the general trends with regard<br />

to EU transport investments in the candidate countries. In how far are actual grants for<br />

transport investment projects in line with the sustainability aspects of EU transport<br />

policy? Are there inconsistencies, and if so, why?<br />

The general ISPA objective and grant requirements were formulated by the<br />

Commission in 1998-1999. The candidate countries themselves then had to formulate<br />

their National Strategy documents and prepare individual projects for funding. These<br />

were then submitted to the ISPA Management Committee for approval. 3<br />

By the end of<br />

2000, all National ISPA Transport Strategies and the initial project lists had been<br />

formulated and submitted to the Commission in Brussels. 4<br />

How much the Commission<br />

2 An assessment of other individual projects, e.g. under Phare, however, is certainly possible, and I do, in<br />

fact, discuss both the contrasting investment rationales and the (present and foreseeable) effects of one<br />

particularly controversial EU-supported transport investment project in CEE, namely the Budapest ring<br />

road, in the following chapter. Also note that evaluations of other individual projects are available in the<br />

literature, although comprehensive assessments of both traffic and land use impacts are rare. With regard<br />

to general evaluations, one particular study deserves special mention: in 1999, the now defunct Evaluation<br />

Unit of the Joint Relex Service of the European Commission (SCR) commissioned the Greek consulting<br />

forms TRADEMCO and SYSTEMA, together with the UK Universities Leeds and Westminster, to carry<br />

out “An Evaluation of Phare-Financed Transport Programmes” (Commission of the European Communities<br />

1999d). Their inventory included 75 program contracts (including those from the Phare multi-country<br />

transport program) and 800 individual contracts. The evaluation was based on a retroactive Logical<br />

Framework (LogFrame) approach. However, it did not operationalize the criterion “sustainability” of<br />

investments in any privileged way. (Also note that although LogFrames are supposed to be the standard for<br />

both IFI and EU project design, monitoring and evaluation, LogFrame matrices were not available for all<br />

projects and thus had to be constructed retroactively.) Most of the key findings were related to the general<br />

relevance of the Phare transport programs to the rapidly changing needs of the candidate countries and<br />

general management efficiency, which was found to be generally mediocre to poor mainly due to delay in<br />

project preparation and implementation, deficiencies in coordination between Phare and the IFIs, the<br />

absence of appropriate strategic/pre-investment studies, as well as lack of sufficient progress in the<br />

restructuring of transport operators (see executive summary, pp. v-viii). Many of these deficiencies seem to<br />

still hold for ISPA as well. Secondly, there has also been “An Evaluation of PHARE and TACIS Co-<br />

Financing Programmes with the EBRD” carried out by Maxwell Stamp for SCR (Commission of the<br />

European Communities 1999e). This study, among other things, presents individual evaluations of two<br />

Phare co-financed transport projects to the Bulgarian and Romanian Railways (both from 1996). The<br />

evaluation criteria were “relevance,” “efficiency,” “effectiveness,” “impact,” and “sustainability.” Yet<br />

statements under the latter heading are non-committal: “Since the full, final impact of these projects cannot<br />

yet be determined conclusively, their sustainability remains somewhat indeterminate at this stage” (p.85).<br />

3 The ISPA Management Committee is the EU body with representatives from all member states which<br />

deals with ISPA matters, also see (Commission of the European Communities 1999g).<br />

4 The first ISPA Annual Report (Commission of the European Communities 2001p:10) clarifies that “the<br />

national ISPA strategies are not intended to be legal documents but should rather be seen as tools to guide


316<br />

shaped the final list of submitted transport projects and which types of projects ultimately<br />

received priority funding are some of the key questions investigated in this chapter. In<br />

how far the resulting ISPA transport infrastructure grants can then be interpreted as an<br />

expression of EU “sustainable transport policy making” is a yet more daunting question. 5<br />

Obviously, issues related to both the “Decisional-Power” and the “Multi-Level<br />

Governance” propositions strongly frame this case study.<br />

Of course, it will be impossible to cover all the manifold political controversies<br />

surrounding each transport mode in detail in this chapter. As it turned out, motorway<br />

plans were by far the most controversial types of investments in both countries, so I<br />

dedicate a disproportionate amount of attention to them in both cases.<br />

Finally, given my study’s declared focus on transport infrastructures, transport<br />

regulatory issues are naturally not analyzed in detail here. Nevertheless, a few issues<br />

need to be emphasized. In addition to the economic transition from a Communist to a<br />

market economy, preparing for EU accession obviously entails profound policy<br />

adjustments in all areas for the CEE candidate countries. Poland and Hungary are both<br />

faced with taking over the EU’s acquis communautaire, i.e. the entire body of EU laws.<br />

Transport law alone represents about 10% of the entire acquis, and it is comprised of<br />

the selection of priority projects for ISPA support.” They can be changed over time, but are always<br />

intended to be consistent with the Accession Partnerships, the National Programmes for the Adoption of the<br />

Acquis, and relevant national planning documents, in particular the National Development Plans (which<br />

candidate countries were still finalizing in 2002). The National ISPA Environment Strategies do not<br />

concern us here. ISPA environment grants are focus on waste-water treatment, water supply and solid<br />

waste management. Note that the ultimate, longer-term, post-accession goal for the ISPA program is a<br />

complete devolution of grant selection responsibility towards national authorities similar to the Cohesion<br />

program<br />

5 As noted in earlier sections of this study, one of the seemingly most hands-on statements of EU transport<br />

policy is the preference it seeks to give to more “sustainable” modes such as rail, combined transport and<br />

public transit in stead of road or air. I will therefore also analyze the modal distribution of EU ISPA grant<br />

investments. We will quickly realize, however, that other issues such as are the scale, the level, timing and<br />

the procedural aspects of the planned investments, as well as the availability of funding from other sources<br />

are equally important categories of analysis.


317<br />

hundreds of EU regulations, directives and decisions. In order to further facilitate their<br />

transposition into national CEE law, DG Transport prepared a comprehensive “Guide to<br />

the Transport Acquis” (Commission of the European Communities 1999f) which gives a<br />

detailed overview of EU transport legislation as of January 1 st , 1999. The Guide’s first<br />

chapter on horizontal issues also includes a section on the TEN Guidelines, the<br />

interoperability of the TEN high-speed rail system and on TEN financial regulations. 6<br />

In<br />

road transport, a vast array of social, technical, fiscal, safety and environmental<br />

requirements are at issue, and some transitional arrangements have been granted already.<br />

For example, both Poland and Hungary have negotiated a gradual increase of axle load<br />

limits on their national road network. In the rail sector, Poland and Hungary also have<br />

resisted full and immediate access to national rail markets and have instead negotiated a<br />

phased approach. Moreover, Poland and Hungary were the only two countries for whom<br />

the EU has proposed provisional closure of the transport chapter which did not see<br />

themselves in a position to implement the EU’s revised railway acquis as of accession. 7<br />

By the time the 2001 Regular Reports were published in November 2001, neither Poland<br />

nor Hungary had fully closed Chapter 9 (Transport Policy) of the acquis. However, by<br />

December 2001 and June 2002, provisional closure was achieved for Hungary and<br />

Poland, respectively. Overall, accession negotiations with both Poland and Hungary are<br />

among the most advanced. 8<br />

6 The whopping 236 page document is available in English, German and French on the DG TREN Website<br />

under http://europa.eu.int/comm/transport/themes/enlargement_policies/english/en.pdf. More importantly,<br />

since December 2001, the document has also been also available in all of the accession country languages<br />

on the DG Enlargement website under http://europa.eu.int/comm/enlargement/docs/index.htm.<br />

7 Also see “Chapter 9 – Transport Policy” under http://europa.eu.int/comm/enlargement/negotiations/<br />

chapters/chap9/ issued June 2002 (last accessed 6-28-2002)<br />

8 For example, the 2001 Regular Reports note the following key progress in the road and rail sectors (see<br />

Commission of the European Communities 2001l; Commission of the European Communities 2001m): In<br />

Poland, the following legislation was adopted: a Program of adjustment of Poland’s Road Network to


318<br />

The rest of this chapter is organized as follows: the next section first situates ISPA<br />

within the longer history of EU and IFI transport sector assistance to Poland and<br />

Hungary. After a general introduction to ISPA and its funding priorities, I then move on<br />

to the two case studies. In both cases, I precede my analysis of the gestation of the<br />

National ISPA Strategy Documents and the priority lists with a discussion of each<br />

country’s key transport infrastructure needs national transport policies. I offer both<br />

preliminary conclusions at the end of each individual case study as well as a set of<br />

concluding remarks at the very end of the chapter.<br />

8.2 EU and IFI Transport Sector Assistance to Poland and Hungary Pre-ISPA<br />

8.2.1 IFI Transport Sector Loans to Poland and Hungary (1990-2001)<br />

IFI co-financing, particularly with the EIB, has been an explicit aim of the ISPA<br />

program. A detailed overview of past IFI funding to Poland and Hungary between 1990<br />

and 2001 is presented in Annex I. Also, detailed analyses of the different roles that the<br />

EIB, the EBRD and the World Bank have played in transport sector funding in CEE have<br />

been presented elsewhere (see especially CEE Bankwatch Network 1997; Feiler and<br />

Stoczkiewiecz 1999; Hook and Peters 1999), and thus need not be repeated here.<br />

However, in order to be able to better assess the magnitude and the importance of these<br />

international investments in relation to ISPA, I nevertheless want to focus on a few key<br />

points that emerge from the data in the various tables in Annex I.<br />

European Union standards, the INTERBUS agreement, a Law on Road Transport , a Law on working time<br />

for drivers, a Law on taxes and local charges, a new Law on railway transport (which includes the creation<br />

of a new Railways Transport Office), a regulation on allocation for railway undertakings, and a Law on<br />

commercialization, restructuring and privatization of the Polish Railway Company PKP. Hungary also<br />

passed the INTERBUS agreement, separated the accounting of railway infrastructure from the accounting<br />

of railway operations, aligned safety belt legislation and the rules for admission to the occupation of road<br />

haulage operation.


319<br />

First, as far as funding for the TINA networks is concerned, one needs to keep in<br />

mind that although international finance has been available for many projects located in<br />

the key TINA corridors, the CEE countries themselves will still be left with vast majority<br />

of the overall investment burden. A few numbers suffice to illustrate this: according to<br />

the TINA Final Report, the total assessed infrastructure needs from 2000 to 2015 amount<br />

to € 36.42 billion in Poland and € 10.16 billion in Hungary, thus theoretically requiring<br />

average annual investments in the amount of € 2.28 billion in Poland and € 635.38<br />

million in Hungary to bring transport infrastructures up to the desired level until 2015.<br />

Investments for the Helsinki corridors alone would require average annual investments in<br />

the amount of € 607 million rail sector and € 784 million road sector investment in<br />

Poland, as well as € 182 million rail sector and € 240 million road sector investments in<br />

Hungary. By contrast, past funding records show that between 1990 and 2000, Poland<br />

was only able to attract an average amount of € 150 to 200 million a year for TINA type<br />

infrastructure investments from international institutions, and Hungary only attracted<br />

about an average € 80-100 million a year. 9<br />

So in the end international funding only ever<br />

covers a fraction of CEEC infrastructure needs. More importantly, IFI assistance comes<br />

largely in the form of loans that will have to be paid back by the governments.<br />

Second, the TINA estimations also show that the road sector should receive no<br />

more than 49%, i.e. less than half of all funds in Poland or Hungary, while the rail sector<br />

should receive at least 40% of all TINA-type infrastructure investments. Contrary to this,<br />

until 2000, the EIB, the EBRD and the World Bank allocated about 70% of their<br />

combined funds in the TINA networks to the road sector. There has thus been a strong<br />

bias towards road investments in past international lending (also see Figure A.1). Many<br />

9 These figures were calculated using data listed in the tables in Annex I and in the TINA Final Report.


320<br />

of these loans, and in particular those from the World Bank, included much needed funds<br />

for upgrading and maintenance rather than for new construction, so it is true that without<br />

taking a closer look at the specific purpose of each loan, this striking statistic ultimately<br />

tells us little about how “sustainable” a particular loan was. Nevertheless, this past bias is<br />

a good indicator that in the absence of particular efforts on the part of both the lender and<br />

the recipient government to the contrary, it is much more difficult to attract international<br />

funds for the rail than for the road sector. One should also remember, however, that<br />

together the road and rail sectors accounted for about 90% of all assessed investment<br />

needs in Poland and Hungary. EU and IFI funding are therefore consistent with needs<br />

assessments at least in the sense that they almost exclusively funded road and rail<br />

infrastructures in Poland and Hungary.<br />

Third and perhaps most important, contrary to ISPA and its predecessors, Phare<br />

and LISF, the IFIs also attributed a sizeable share of their loans in Hungary and Poland<br />

towards urban transport projects. Citing the principle of subsidiarity as the central<br />

reason, the EU currently leaves funding for public transit entirely to its house-bank, the<br />

EIB. I will return to this problematic issue both in this and in the following chapter. It<br />

certainly seems a bitter irony that at a time where official European Union transport<br />

policy is more actively than ever favoring rail and urban public transit as “more<br />

sustainable modes,” there is currently no funding mechanism available for channeling<br />

any EU transport sector grants into urban areas other than for ring roads and bypasses<br />

forming part of the Helsinki corridors.


321<br />

8.2.2 EU Transport Sector Grants Pre-ISPA: Phare and LISF (1990-1999)<br />

As noted above, ISPA was only instituted in 1999. The European Union's<br />

comprehensive proposal for coherent accession assistance to CEE was first set out in<br />

Agenda 2000 (Commission of the European Communities 1997d; Commission of the<br />

European Communities 1997e), which specifically mentions the creation of the new<br />

ISPA instrument. ISPA was designed to complement and in part supersede the EU’s<br />

older Phare grant program and the LSIF. 10<br />

In order to also better contextualize the ISPA<br />

program within the longer post-transition history of EU grant assistance, the following<br />

section presents a short review of EU transport infrastructure grants to CEECs from the<br />

early 1990s.<br />

The EU’s first grant assistance instrument, the so-called Phare program was<br />

originally instituted in 1989 to coordinate EC assistance toward Poland and Hungary. 11<br />

After the 1994 European Council meeting in Essen, Phare became the EU’s main<br />

program for grant assistance for the CEE candidate countries. From 1990 to 1994, the<br />

program allocated 4.2 billion ECU, a sum that was increased to 6.7 billion in the<br />

following programming period from 1995 to 1999. However, it was only after the<br />

Luxembourg European Council in 1997 officially launched the present enlargement<br />

process that Phare became a true “pre-accession” instrument. This also meant that Phare<br />

became a less demand-driven instrument, since the EU began setting out its own list of<br />

10 LISF (Large-Scale Infrastructure Facility) was a short-lived, Phare-funded pre-cursor to ISPA. From<br />

1998-99, the LISF was intended to cover the transition from Phare to ISPA by funding select large-scale<br />

infrastructure projects in the candidate states, with an emphasis on co-financing with the IFIs. It was<br />

primarily for this purpose that the EC, the EBRD and the World Bank signed a Memorandum of<br />

Understanding in March 1998 setting out the means and method of their enhanced cooperation. Also see<br />

Commission of the European Communities (1999d:5).<br />

11<br />

The (francophone) acronym PHARE meant “Poland and Hungary - Assistance for Economic<br />

Reconstruction.” The acronym became common usage so it was kept even after the program was extended<br />

to include other countries. Detailed information about the Phare program can be found under<br />

http://europa.eu.int/comm/enlargement/pas/phare/index.htm, last accessed on 6-21-2002.


322<br />

short and medium priorities for the candidate states. Since then Phare funding focuses on<br />

priorities set down in the countries’ Accession Partnerships. In 1999, Phare orientations<br />

were then adjusted again in order to clarify the relationship of Phare to the other new preaccession<br />

instruments, “so as to redirect the Phare funds that were liberated by the arrival<br />

of SAPARD and ISPA from rural development and from selected infrastructure projects<br />

in the sectors of transport and environment towards the area of economic and social<br />

cohesion.” 12<br />

Hence, Phare is now considered the pre-accession instrument for regional<br />

development. The program currently concentrates on institution building and investment<br />

support as the two main types of assistance. 13<br />

Figure 8.1 gives an overview of the<br />

evolution of Phare funding in the two CEE countries to first receive grant support, Poland<br />

and Hungary. The share of infrastructure related to total funding jumps from 13% to<br />

45% in Poland and from 2% to 34% in Hungary after 1994, with the percentages<br />

remaining relatively stable after that. In the coming funding period, investment support<br />

is to account for about 70% of the entire Phare budget, and it is to be closely linked to the<br />

adoption of the acquis communautaire. With the complementing of Phare by the two<br />

new pre-accession instruments ISPA and Sapard after 2000, overall grant aid to CEE<br />

12 See http://europa.eu.int/comm/enlargement/pas/phare/, Section 1.2 “Phare Orientations” (last accessed 6-<br />

21-2002).<br />

13 Note, however, that Phare grants after 1999/2000 always also included some funding for concrete<br />

transport infrastructure projects at the local/regional level. However, due to limits in the scope of this<br />

chapter, these Phare transport projects are not analyzed in detail here. Institution building and technical<br />

assistance accounted for a major part of early Phare transport-sector funding, with grants being mainly used<br />

for feasibility studies. However, when regulations were changed to allow Phare to use an increasing share<br />

of its budget for project co-financing with other financial institutions in 1994, overall spending on concrete<br />

infrastructure projects increased greatly. For 2001, the initial Phare budget amounted to € 1634 million, of<br />

which Poland received € 411 million, i.e. about one fourth, and Hungary € 90 million. Additionally, it was<br />

possible for countries to receive funds as part of multi-country grants via the cross-border allocations (€<br />

163) and the regional and horizontal allocations (€ 230 million).


323<br />

countries will increase substantially, likely accounting for at as much as 2 billion Euro in<br />

infrastructure development. 14<br />

Looking at Phare’s past record in transport sector funding, we can see that Phare<br />

grants were also biased in favor of road projects. Figure 8.2 reveals that 53% percent of a<br />

total 884.2 million ECU disbursed were allocated to road, while only 32% went to rail.<br />

This modal bias is still odds with the mode-specific assessed needs of the recipient<br />

countries, and it remains to be seen if ISPA will finally reverse this trend.<br />

Figure 8.1 PHARE Funds for Hungary and Poland per Sector 1990-97 (in MECU)<br />

800<br />

700<br />

Infrastructure (energy,<br />

transport,<br />

telecommunications)<br />

13%<br />

600<br />

500<br />

400<br />

2%<br />

Other sectors<br />

300<br />

200<br />

100<br />

34% 39% 26% 33%<br />

45% 52%<br />

58%<br />

47%<br />

0<br />

1990-<br />

1993<br />

1994 1995 1996 1997 1990-<br />

Hungary<br />

1993<br />

1994 1995 1996 1997<br />

Poland<br />

Source: Own compilation using data from the EU Phare Program<br />

14 The budget for Sapard, the pre-accession instrument for agricultural and rural development aid, is<br />

significantly smaller than ISPA, accounting for 520 million a year. The 2 billion per year in infrastructure<br />

development consist of the about 1 billion of Phare’s annual total of 1.5 billion which will go for<br />

infrastructure investment, and ISPA, of which 500 million will go directly to transport infrastructure.


324<br />

Figure 8.2<br />

EU Transport Grants to CEEC pre-ISPA (Phare 1990-97 and LISF 1998-99)<br />

Airports &<br />

Ports<br />

5%<br />

Railways<br />

34%<br />

Other<br />

7%<br />

Roads &<br />

Highways<br />

54%<br />

Total funds<br />

disbursed:<br />

978 MECU<br />

Source: Own Compilation using data from the EU Phare Program<br />

8.3 A Precursor to Cohesion Funding? Overview of ISPA Priorities<br />

In its final agreed form, ISPA evenly divides a total of € 1.04 billion a year at<br />

1999 prices between transport infrastructure and environment projects for the next six<br />

years.<br />

ISPA is strongly accession-oriented, and will closely follow the format of the<br />

Cohesion Fund. However, since contrary to the Cohesion Fund, ISPA is dealing with<br />

applicant, rather than member states, the distribution of funds is not decentralized (yet)<br />

but requires ex-ante approval of tendering and contracting. 15<br />

The country-by-country<br />

allocation is based on three criteria: population, per capita GDP and land surface area.<br />

Table 8.1 shows the per country allocation, given by the Commission as a range. Poland<br />

alone is thus to receive roughly one third of all ISPA grants, Hungary less than one tenth.<br />

All countries have to submit National ISPA Strategy Papers and present a coherent<br />

investment plan. Only very small portions of ISPA money will be used for preparatory<br />

studies and technical assistance. The leveraging of additional international co-financing<br />

15 However, a recent DG Regio paper (CEC, DG Regio 2000) notes that “Coordination regulation 1266/99<br />

of 21 June 1999 (art 12.2) opens the possibility for waiving the ex-ant approval requirement and for<br />

conferring on implementation agencies management of aid on a decentralized basis. This will however<br />

only be decided on the basis of a case by case analysis of the management capacity, financial control<br />

procedures and structures regarding public finance.”


325<br />

is also an explicit goal. The general eligibility criteria further specify that individual<br />

measures should have a cost of at least 5 million Euros in order to be of a significant<br />

scale to have an impact on network development. The Commission will grant up to 75%<br />

of total project cost, and while ISPA is not to be combined with other pre-accession<br />

funding (i.e. Phare), loans by IFIs, including the EIB, are encouraged as co-funding.<br />

Combined assistance under ISPA and other Community aid is not to exceed 90% of total<br />

expenditure of a project. Exceptionally, up to 2 % of a country’s total ISPA allocation<br />

may be used to fund preliminary studies, environmental assessments and additional<br />

technical assistance related to ISPA priority projects, and in these cases ISPA may<br />

finance up to 100 % of the total project cost.<br />

Table 8.1: Per Country Allocation for ISPA Transport Grants<br />

Country<br />

Surface<br />

Area<br />

(km²)<br />

Population<br />

in 1997<br />

(Million)<br />

Index of GDP<br />

per inhabitant<br />

(average = 100)<br />

Indicative<br />

Allocation<br />

(percent)<br />

Indicative<br />

Allocation<br />

(Million €)<br />

Poland 312685 38.66 91 30 - 37% 156 - 192.4<br />

Hungary 93030 10.15 124 7 - 10% 36.4 - 52.0<br />

Bulgaria 111062 8.31 67 8 - 12% 41.6 - 62.4<br />

Czech Republic 78864 10.3 166 5.5 - 8% 28.6 - 41.6<br />

Estonia 43431 1.46 90 2 - 3.5% 10.4 - 18.2<br />

Lithuania 65300 3.7 76 4 - 6% 20.8 - 31.2<br />

Latvia 64589 2.47 67 3.5 - 5.5% 18.2 - 28.6<br />

Romania 238391 22.55 84 20 - 26% 104 -135.2<br />

Slovenia 20256 1.97 175 1 – 2% 5.2 - 10.4<br />

Slovakia 49035 5.38 116 3.5 - 5.5% 18.2 - 28.6<br />

Source: http://www.europa.eu.int/comm/regional_policy/funds/ispa/provisions_en.htm<br />

(Last accessed on 6-20-2002) and Commission of the European Communities (1999g:5)<br />

All in all, ISPA remains a somewhat curious, hybrid funding instrument. One<br />

Commission expert called it “an elastic category of accession.” Much of it has to do with


326<br />

the particulars of Eastern enlargement, which is also a process of flexible date setting.<br />

ISPA is neither a true pre-accession version of the Cohesion fund (although that is clearly<br />

its closest pendant within the internal EU family of funds) nor is it comparable to nonaccession<br />

related external aid which the EU provides to non-accession third countries via<br />

EuropAid.<br />

Remember also that of the three pre-accession instruments which – upon<br />

accession - are to be transitioned into regular EU funding instruments, Phare, and not<br />

ISPA, is the program which is devised as the precursor to regional development funding.<br />

Consequently, (economic and social) cohesion does not feature as a prominent storyline<br />

justifying ISPA transport interventions. This also means, however, that transport<br />

infrastructure investments in Poland and Hungary which largely serve regional or local<br />

development objectives, e.g. rural access roads outside the TINA network, while not<br />

eligible for ISPA funds, might still be still be eligible for EU funding under the Phare<br />

program. Given this “division of labor” between the different EU funding instruments, it<br />

interesting to note that the term “cohesion” nevertheless appears in the very first article of<br />

the Council Regulation establishing ISPA. Article 1 sets out the “Definition and<br />

Objective” of the instrument as follows (Council of the European Communities 1999):<br />

ISPA shall provide assistance to contribute to the preparation for accession to the<br />

European Union of the [hereby defined] “beneficiary countries'” in the area of<br />

economic and social cohesion, concerning environment and transport policies in<br />

accordance with the provisions of this Regulation. (my emphasis)<br />

Of course, the relationship between economic and social cohesion and<br />

environmental and transport policies is purely implied. Article 2 of the regulation then<br />

sets out the particular eligibility measures for the ISPA program, also specifying which<br />

function they must fulfill within the international or national transport network:


327<br />

1. The Community assistance financed under ISPA shall include projects, stages of a<br />

project which are technically and financially independent, groups of projects or project<br />

schemes in the field of environment or transport, hereinafter referred to collectively as<br />

“measures”. A stage of a project may also cover preliminary, feasibility and technical<br />

studies needed for carrying out a project.<br />

2. The Community shall provide assistance under ISPA in the light of the objectives<br />

mentioned in Article 1 for the following:<br />

[(a) environmental measures]; (b) transport infrastructure measures which promote<br />

sustainable mobility, and in particular those that constitute projects of common<br />

interest based on the criteria of Decision No 1692/96/EC and those which enable the<br />

beneficiary countries to comply with the objectives of the Accession Partnerships; this<br />

includes interconnection and interoperability of national networks as well as with the<br />

trans-European networks together with access to such networks. 16<br />

Note that no particular reference is made to either the TINA backbone or the<br />

TINA additional network.<br />

Nevertheless, commission representatives repeatedly<br />

emphasized that ISPA transport funding is to be primarily allocated towards major<br />

infrastructure investments along the Helsinki Corridors. It is therefore interesting to see<br />

how this particular wording has since reappeared in somewhat different phrasings in<br />

several less official Commission documents designed to explain the eligibility of ISPA.<br />

The wording in the DG Regio’s document “ISPA mandate, programming and<br />

implementation – State of Play” is still very close to the phrasing in the regulation (see<br />

Commission of the European Communities 2000a). The same can be said about the<br />

wording on the official website of the European Delegation in Poland. 17<br />

16 This article re-appears as Article 3 in a Council regulation clarifying the relationship between ISPA and<br />

PHARE. Article 2 of this “Council Regulation (EC) No 1266/1999 of 21 June 1999 on coordinating aid to<br />

the applicant countries in the framework of the pre-accession strategy and amending Regulation (EEC) No<br />

3906/89” (Council of the European Communities 1999) amends the Phare Regulation as follows:<br />

Regulation (EEC) No 3906/89 is hereby amended by adding a new paragraph 3 to Article 3 to read as<br />

follows:<br />

For applicant countries with accession partnerships with the European Union, funding under the<br />

PHARE programme shall focus on the main priorities for the adoption of the acquis communautaire, i.e.<br />

building up the administrative and institutional capacities of the applicant States and investment, except<br />

for the type of investments financed in accordance with Regulations (EC) No 1267/1999 (*) and (EC)<br />

No 1268/1999 (**). PHARE funding may also be used to finance the measures in the fields of<br />

environment, transport and agricultural and rural development which form an incidental but<br />

indispensable part of integrated industrial reconstruction or regional development programmes.<br />

17 The exact wording in the DG Regio document is as follows:


328<br />

By contrast, the DG Regio information brochure “ISPA in a nutshell” presents an<br />

interpretation which much more clearly privileges investments in the Helsinki corridors:<br />

ISPA co-finances projects in the major road and rail corridors in the candidate<br />

countries, identified at the Helsinki and Crete Conferences, including connections<br />

between national networks and links to the Trans-European transport Networks within<br />

the Union. 18<br />

Meanwhile, the EU delegation in Hungary provides the interested public with an<br />

even more creative interpretation. On their official website, they explain the ISPA<br />

criteria as follows:<br />

In the case of transport projects under ISPA, they must be an extension of a TEN<br />

network, one of the priority corridors which the Commission is recommending, or an<br />

access road to such a network. 19<br />

So access roads suddenly receive a particular mention, but nothing is said about<br />

either road or rail projects being eligible because they increase the interconnectivity of<br />

national networks. This much more restrictive interpretation is particularly interesting in<br />

light of the fact that the EU delegation website for Hungary, which is also available in<br />

Hungarian, is likely to be the first and perhaps even only source of information consulted<br />

by Hungarian stakeholders interested in ISPA eligibility criteria.<br />

Projects that encourage sustainable forms of moving people and goods, in particular projects which are<br />

of Community interest, and project which enable the countries concerned to meet the objectives of the<br />

Accession Partnerships. This will include providing good connections between the Trans-European<br />

transport networks and road and rail corridors (identified at the Helsinki and Crete Conference [sic]) in<br />

the applicant countries and interconnections between national networks and links from them to the<br />

Trans-European transport Networks.<br />

On the website of the EU Delegation in Poland this reads as follows:<br />

The investments in the field of transport infrastructure should encourage sustainable forms of mobility<br />

and compose of projects which are of general interest on the basis of the Decision's No. 1692/96/WE<br />

criteria and projects which will provide good interconnections between national networks and links<br />

from them to the trans-European transport networks.<br />

See http://www.europa.delpol.pl/english/podstrona.php?url=/english/III/3.php, accessed Aug 22 nd , 2002<br />

18 CEC [, 2002b #1526], also see http://europa.eu.int/comm/regional_policy/funds/ispa/pdf/nutsh6.pdf . It<br />

should also be noted previous editions of this two-page brochure in 2001used identical phrasing.<br />

19 See http://www.eudelegation.hu/delegacio/elocsatlakozas_ispa_en.html, accessed on Aug 22 nd , 2002


329<br />

During the High-Level Meeting in Brussels, March 2000, Guy Crauser, then<br />

Director General for Regional Policy at the Commission, delivered a speech which was<br />

supposed to clarify the aims of structural and cohesion funding in Member states and<br />

their relationship to pre-accession funding to the applicant countries. The ISPA-relevant<br />

excerpts from this speech are also well-worth considering in detail. Turning to ISPA,<br />

Crauser began by saying the following (Crauser 2000):<br />

As you all know, ISPA will be a major new source of investment in the transport and<br />

environment sectors. ISPA is not an environmental or a transport policy<br />

instrument. ISPA has been designed as a precursor of the Cohesion and Structural<br />

Funds. It is hence part of the family of financial support instruments for economic<br />

and social cohesion. ISPA's principal aim is therefore to lay the foundations for<br />

the future Structural Funds by providing the authorities here with the experience of<br />

managing large-scale strategic investments in partnership with the Commission. This<br />

experience will be invaluable when the time comes to manage larger and more<br />

complex investment programmes supported by the Structural Funds. (Emphasis<br />

added.)<br />

Just a few moments later, however, we find the following remarks:<br />

ISPA's aims are ambitious: it will support major investments which make a real<br />

difference to the transport system and to the quality of the environment … I<br />

understand that there has been some confusion as to the scope of the different<br />

instruments. ISPA is a precursor of an economic and social cohesion support<br />

mechanism but not an instrument of regional policy and not an instrument for<br />

rural development. ISPA beneficiaries are entire countries with their whole territory.<br />

ISPA is targeted to the trans-European transport corridors and to investment into<br />

the environmental acquis. (Emphasis added.)<br />

In the end, Crauser himself did little to end the confusion over ISPA, but rather<br />

exacerbated it. How can an instrument not be a transport policy instrument when it is<br />

explicitly aiming to make a difference in the recipient’s transport system by targeting<br />

Trans-European transport corridors? How can an instrument not be a regional policy<br />

instrument when it is a) being administered by the Directorate General for Regional<br />

Policy and b) considered to be part of “a family of instruments for economic and social


330<br />

cohesion”? And if ISPA is neither a transport nor a regional policy instrument, what is it<br />

exactly, then, other than a random pre-accession hand-out? Given the elaborate criteria<br />

and policy documents relating to ISPA, ISPA is all but a random instrument, of course.<br />

The fact remains that, as Chapter 7 already indicated and as will be demonstrated<br />

in more detail below, the prospect of receiving ISPA grants profoundly shaped national<br />

transport policy considerations in the recipient countries. So de facto, ISPA is clearly an<br />

EU instrument influencing CEE transport policy, despite the semantic acrobatics of the<br />

EU’s Regional Policy Director to the contrary.<br />

Apart from generic references to the favoring of environmentally friendly modes,<br />

neither the ISPA Council Regulation not any other supplementary materials contain any<br />

specifications on modal allocations. It is thus possible that similar to the EU Cohesion<br />

Fund as well as Phare and IFI funding in CEE, ISPA will end up disproportionably<br />

benefiting the road sector. Of course this has to be looked at on a case by case basis,<br />

since much also depends on what the different countries desire to submit for ISPA<br />

funding. This is why I begin each of the two case study reviews on National ISPA<br />

funding in Poland and Hungary with some preliminary remarks about the national<br />

transport policy context after the transition.<br />

8.4 EU ISPA Transport Funding for Poland<br />

8.4.1 The National Context: Polish Transport Policy (Post-Transition)<br />

Polish national transport policy underwent several profound changes before the<br />

ISPA strategy was formulated in 1999 - 2000. A comprehensive post-transition transport<br />

policy document, the so-called Polish Transport White Paper (Polityka transportowa,


331<br />

MTME 1995) was elaborated in 1994/1995 by a Social Democrat. It displays the typical<br />

optimism of transport’s economic benefits including<br />

an increasing quality of life for the population of the country, the development of new<br />

investments in particular regions of the country, ... decreasing unemployment,...<br />

promoting the development of old and new sectors of industry, reinvigorating the<br />

economies of declining regions and small and medium towns, easing the transfer to the<br />

country of foreign technology, and speeding the integration with European countries.<br />

(MTME 1995, as translated and quoted in Judge 2000)<br />

The paper was considered neither a consistent nor a consensual policy document.<br />

As Taylor (1998:227) summarizes:<br />

Irrespective of the real impact of this document on the realization of transport policy,<br />

it illustrates the way of thinking and preferences of the Ministry of Transport and<br />

Maritime Economy. On one hand, it speaks of necessary changes, more economic<br />

autonomy and financial balance for transport, while on the other, it is against full<br />

privatization and deregulation in transport. Moreover, its discussion of how to finance<br />

transport and its approach to ecological problems, are mostly controversial.<br />

It is of course impossible to pass judgment on this paper without entering a<br />

normative debate on policy and investment preferences. Most important from the point<br />

of view of my study, however, is the fact that the policy was attacked from a great variety<br />

of perspectives which together almost represented the entire bandwidth of sustainable<br />

transport-related discursive frameworks. Neither the IFIs nor the EU were content with<br />

the policy, largely due to its lacking commitment to full liberalization and transition to<br />

market principles. National transport policy experts found traffic forecasts to be<br />

unrealistic and missed a clear and transparent elaboration of infrastructure investments<br />

priorities. The environmental movement hoped for greater support for rail and wanted to<br />

stop the motorway construction program. Given its anti-market, protectionist approach in<br />

key areas of transport policy (particularly in the airline sector), as well as its lack of any


332<br />

clear environmental commitments, the 1994/5 White Paper can thus not be characterized<br />

as a typical ecological modernization policy paper. Even as a basic infrastructure<br />

modernization program it was rightfully considered lacking by both national and<br />

international experts. In this sense, Polish national transport policy of the mid-1990s was<br />

thus still rather different from both EU member state policy at the national level, as well<br />

as from EU transport policy as a whole.<br />

The most controversial element of the policy was its approach to motorway<br />

expansion. In 1996, two of the country’s leading environmental non-governmental<br />

organizations, the research-oriented Institute for Sustainable Development and the more<br />

activist/advocacy-oriented Polish Ecological Club, therefore assembled a team of<br />

internationally respected Polish experts, drafted an “Alternative Transport Policy for<br />

Poland” (Instytut na Rzecz Ekorozwojo (Institute for Sustainable Development) 1996)<br />

and challenged the national government to a debate. When the World Bank then agreed<br />

to host a seminar on the topic in April 1998, the new government could do little but<br />

accept the challenge. The ensuing debate between the Ministry of Transport – headed by<br />

the Minister himself – and the environmentalists was closely followed by the European<br />

Commission and IFI representatives. Noting that “Poland is notable for its vigorous<br />

community of organizations concerned about the environment,” the World Bank<br />

summarized the key issues of the debate as follows (World Bank 1999:33-34):<br />

[The Alternative Transport Policy] showed that extrapolation of the Government’s<br />

present policies – supportive of private car use and road transport generally,<br />

construction of motorways, and neglect of urban public transport – would carry a<br />

much higher environmental cost than a strongly pro-public transport, pro-rail, antiprivate<br />

cars policy. The analysis omits assessment of the economic benefits from<br />

greater travel and transport, so remains only partial. It does not address the question<br />

of what policy instruments could achieve the environmentally-friendly scenarios, and<br />

what effort – chiefly political – would be needed.


333<br />

In fact, the World Bank agreed with the NGOs that the key political efforts<br />

needed were a revision of Polish Motorway policy, and renewed attention to rail. Yet<br />

while the NGO’s call for a reevaluation of the government’s over-ambitious highway<br />

construction program was chiefly motivated by environmental reasons, World Bank<br />

skepticism, quite predictably, was based on economic arguments. The World Bank’s<br />

official road-sector recommendation to the Polish government is worth citing at length<br />

here (World Bank 1999:i-ii):<br />

Major investments in transport infrastructure, including motorways, are clearly<br />

required as Poland’s economy continues its rapid growth and as it prepares for<br />

accession to the EU. However, … considering the competing demands of the State<br />

budget for financing many other investments in social and physical infrastructure, we<br />

recommend that the Motorway agency and the Ministry of Transport revisit the timing<br />

and phasing of the motorway program and look at other alternatives which could still<br />

meet Poland’s transport needs in the coming years, but at lower cost. … [Private<br />

concessions have] turned out not to be viable. … The A1 and the A2 sections as now<br />

planned are separate segments which would not for the time being be linked with<br />

other motorway segments, but yet be built as full dual carriageways with gradeseparated<br />

interchanges. This phasing is not the most economic. Several other options<br />

could be considered. One would be to look again at options for improving existing<br />

roads … as a first step and postpone major motorway construction until traffic is<br />

much higher. Another option is to start work on the motorway program, but to<br />

concentrate first on completing the main trans-European motorway (working<br />

outwards from Warsaw)…. All this will require rewriting of the Motorway Laws. The<br />

Motorways Agency has received abundant advice on options before it, the time has<br />

come for decisions. Which sections should be built first? What staging will be most<br />

economic? Which risks should be borne by the State and which by the concessionaire?<br />

… What decision criteria should be adopted? [Emphasis added]<br />

For one, this quote aptly summarizes the key deficiencies of the Polish motorway<br />

plans. Additionally, it is a dramatic reminder that an ecological modernization approach<br />

that is consistently complemented by a neo-liberal fiscal federalism perspective (typically<br />

exemplified by the World Bank) in fact tends to favor more moderate (and thus also<br />

lower-impact) infrastructure construction plans than modernization approaches that are


334<br />

chiefly guided by political and/or Keynesian pro-investment rationales (exemplified by<br />

the Polish as well as some EU governments). Assuming larger “structural” benefits, the<br />

latter are always less concerned about the particular financial costs and benefits of<br />

individual infrastructure projects. 20<br />

However, as Judge (2000:488) concluded in a recent<br />

review of the regional and environmental dimensions of Polish motorway policy,<br />

despite government rhetoric about the regional benefits of the motorway system, there<br />

is no published research on where these benefits might arise. … Instead, the strategic<br />

development aspects have de facto been submerged by financing issues, the drive to<br />

enter the European Union and controversy over the environmental impact.<br />

Lastly, it should be obvious that the World Bank’s suggestion to privilege<br />

highway investments in the Pan-European corridors around Warsaw was of course well<br />

suited to the EU’s strategic interests.<br />

The Polish government remained reluctant to give up its vast motorway<br />

ambitions, however. It is highly revealing that in this context, TINA was portrayed by<br />

the Polish government as an “EU initiative” that is “encouraging” a particular set of<br />

infrastructures, and not as the Pan-European effort to deliver an objective CEE needs<br />

assessment that it purported to be. Otherwise, the government showed itself amenable to<br />

various reform ideas in the rail and public transport sectors, but firm in its commitment<br />

towards motorway construction. Finally, the government also made it very clear that the<br />

NGOs’ renunciation-type demands of advocating lower levels of traffic stood no chance<br />

under the current political regime. 21<br />

20 Remember that there are increasing empirical challenges to this Keynesian governmental pro-growth<br />

infrastructure-building argument (also see the relevant sections of chapters 2 and 6).<br />

21 The actual summary points presented by the Polish government during the debate over the Alternative<br />

Transport Policy were as follows (Attachment 2, World Bank 1999:34):<br />

Yes, the Ministry will take environmental concerns into account.<br />

It will be hard to stop the motorway program.


335<br />

However, due to renewed shifts in the Polish political landscape of power,<br />

circumstances changed dramatically again just before the Polish National ISPA Strategy<br />

was supposed to be drafted. Interestingly, Jan Friedberg, the Ex-Deputy Major of<br />

Krakow and a long-time supporter of Polish Ecological Club initiatives, became Deputy<br />

Minister of Transport and Under Secretary of State. Friedberg had already acquired an<br />

international reputation as a savvy sustainable transport expert by being one of the key<br />

promoters of the much acclaimed Krakow Fast Tram urban transport project (supported<br />

financially by the EBRD, the EIB and Phare). Most importantly, Friedberg had also been<br />

one of the co-authors of the Polish Alternative Transport Policy of 1998. Knowing that<br />

he had several influential political adversaries both inside his ministry and inside the<br />

Motorway Agency, and that his time as Under Secretary of State might therefore be<br />

limited, Friedberg wasted little in reworking Polish transport policy. 22<br />

In some short fullday<br />

(and night) working sessions in June 2000, a new draft transport policy was<br />

developed with the help of key national experts. Although neither finished nor approved<br />

at the time that the Polish ISPA transport strategy was finished (January 2000), this<br />

background certainly explains the shift in tone compared to previous Polish transport<br />

policy statements. However, while generally hailed as a much more consistent overall<br />

approach, one national expert nevertheless warned that, as usual, the devil lay in the<br />

As part of Poland’s preparing for EU access, the EU, though its Transport Infrastructure Needs<br />

Assessment initiative, is encouraging investment in major transport infrastructure supported by IFI<br />

financing.<br />

We will try to factor externalities into our project, but much remains to be done to give them monetary<br />

values.<br />

We agree that rail has an economic advantage for long-distance, mass transportation.<br />

Rail lines not of national interest can now be devolved to regional governments.<br />

We accept that the State should take urban transport under its wing in a “strategic thinking process.”<br />

Limiting mobility goes against out basic policy of free choice in transport, so it is asking a lot to suggest<br />

the Government to do so.<br />

22 Jan Friedberg in fact managed to remain in his position until the latest elections in 2001.


336<br />

details, and that the details of the new policy were not always necessarily more<br />

sustainable. Either way, the new Polish policy is now more consistently set within an<br />

overall framework of ecological modernization that heeds to market forces. In its draft<br />

amended 2001 version, the main goal of Polish transport policy is the “creation of a<br />

transport system which would be sustainable in terms technology, economy, spatial,<br />

social and environmental aspects; this should be achieved while developing a market<br />

economy and taking into account international competition” (Republic of Poland 2000;<br />

ECMT 2001:11).<br />

8.4.2 The Polish ISPA Transport Strategy and Its Priorities<br />

According to the Under Secretary of State Jan Friedberg, he himself drafted the<br />

introductory texts of the Polish ISPA transport strategy. The Commission representatives<br />

were rather pleased with the document, finding it to be the most competent one among<br />

the submitted national strategies. The ISPA document is well organized and structured.<br />

An introductory section reviews ISPA guidelines and requirements. Here, the mention<br />

that in Poland, “the quality of the infrastructure is a bottleneck in efficient transport<br />

operations” (p. 4) is interesting inasmuch as it renders an important, alternative meaning<br />

to the key term bottleneck: what seems needed most in the Polish case is an overall<br />

modernization of the existing infrastructure, rather than a focus on particular high-profile<br />

international priority projects. This important strategic view is shared by several key<br />

Polish experts (see especially the quote from Prof. Suchorzewski’s ECMT Report in the<br />

concluding section of this chapter). In the following section of the document, which


337<br />

describes Polish transport sector trends from 1990-1998, the following key statistics are<br />

notable:<br />

?? the dramatic, 70% increase in the number of road vehicles,<br />

?? the fact that road transport now accounts for 80% of cargo by weight and for 40% of<br />

ton-km, the 50% fall in passenger rail transport,<br />

?? the two-thirds increase of airport traffic, the increase of border traffic resulting in<br />

about 270 million people crossing the borders in 1997,<br />

?? rising numbers of accidents resulting in about 7000 fatalities a year, and finally,<br />

?? the substantial deterioration of the road network over the last decade due to limited<br />

funds from the state budget.<br />

With regard to the road network, the profile section (p.7ff) then also points to the<br />

lack of a developed, limited access expressway network as well as the fact that at present,<br />

less than 50% of Polish roads are even adjusted to axle loads of 100 kN, while the EU<br />

standards is 115 kN. With regard to the rail sector, only about 60% of the lines are in<br />

good or very good condition, and many lines have reserve capacity. The following<br />

sections on medium term “strategic aims for transport infrastructure development” and on<br />

the “method of selection of projects to be co-financed by ISPA” prepare the way for the<br />

concrete suggestions presented in the final sections. Besides basic compliance with<br />

formal requirements concerning maturity and size of the projects and other elements of<br />

the EU’s ISPA regulation, the document takes particular care to assure compliance with<br />

the preference for Helsinki Corridor location, although the authors of the document,<br />

writing in somewhat twisted, non-native sentence constructions, still clearly attempt to<br />

keep the door open for other projects:<br />

During the selection of projects in Poland, it has been taken into account that the<br />

projects put forward for ISPA financing must be situated on the main routes of<br />

international importance, which after the accession to the EU will become the part of<br />

TENs. The list of these routes for all the candidate countries, identified as the ‘TINA<br />

network’, have been agreed by all the involved countries and approved by the<br />

European Commission. The basic components of this network are the connections


338<br />

within the frame of the Pan-European Transport Corridors systems established on the<br />

Crete conference (1994) and Helsinki conference (1997). Four Pan-European<br />

corridors crossing Poland and the projects located in these Corridors will be the<br />

investment priorities in the years 2000-2006 and in the later period. … Moreover, in<br />

the context of ISPA funds and IFI loans participation in the financing of the<br />

infrastructure projects, the important investments (from the point of view of the<br />

development of the country’s transport system) could be placed in the rest of the<br />

components of TINA network and would supplement, in the necessary scope, the<br />

framework created by the corridors.<br />

Of particular interest here is the mention of the national perspective, hinting at<br />

dissonances between European and national level priorities. Before presenting the list of<br />

priority projects, the document then also has an additional section on “sources of<br />

financing: aims, principles and assumptions.” Here, the Polish government assures the<br />

EU that they will apply “principles of sound management” and quote a series elements<br />

from their national document “Strategy for public finance and economical development,<br />

Poland 2000-2010. 23<br />

In the end, weighing the suitability of ISPA grant funding for<br />

possible projects against sources from the state budget, from local authority budgets,<br />

private sector contributions, IFI and other bilateral loans, and Phare grants (for regional<br />

infrastructure), the Polish ISPA document presents a list of projects which would, if<br />

executed, exceed the foreseen Polish ISPA allocation for the 2000-2006 period.<br />

Originally, Polish officials were interested in presenting an even wider selection of<br />

projects to DG Regio in Brussels. However, they were strongly encouraged by the<br />

responsible DG Regio officer to concentrate on select TEN corridors, and more precisely<br />

on Helsinki Corridors II and III. These are the same stretches of motorways and railways<br />

23 This document, among other things, assumes that “state budget expenditures for transport infrastructure<br />

will increase from PLN 5.7 billion in 2000 to PLN 11.6 in 2006, i.e. from 0.8% of GDP in 2000 to 1.0% of<br />

GDP in 2006” (Republic of Poland 2000:15). Using 2002 exchange rates, this amounts to € 1.5 in 2000 and<br />

€ 3 in 2006. By comparison, TINA assumed average annual expenditures of € 1.3 from 2000 to 2015 just<br />

for Helsinki corridor expenditure in the road and rail sectors, as well as an additional € 0.8 for additional<br />

TINA lines and infrastructure nodes.


339<br />

that had previously received most Phare and IFI funding. This strategic focus was then<br />

consistently integrated into the formulation of the Polish ISPA Transport Strategy. At the<br />

point that the document was published, the projects for submission in 2000 had already<br />

been chosen, and all three had received funding. Table 8.2 presents an overview of both<br />

the planned ISPA projects until 2006 and those that had received funding until December<br />

31, 2001.<br />

Table 8.2 Overview of ISPA Transport Grants to Poland<br />

ISPA Transport Grants to Poland TINA Planned Approved<br />

(in Million €) Location? ('00-'06) ('00-'01)<br />

Modernization E-20 Railline Rzeptin-Border Corridor II 30,00 17,72<br />

Modernization of the Poznan rail node E-20 Corridor II 200,00 50,58<br />

Rail Improvements / Liquidation of Bottlenecks Corridors & Add. 83,25<br />

Modernization E-30 Railline Wegliniec-Legnica Corridor III 186,00 92,84<br />

Technical Assistance Modernization E-65 Railline Corridor VI 5,96<br />

Modernization E-65 Railline Warsaw-Dzialdowo Corridor VI 270,00<br />

Modernization E-20 Railline Siedlce - Terespol Corridor II 288,00<br />

PERCENTAGE OF GRANTS RAIL SECTOR 40% 46%<br />

Construction A4 Highway Klesczów - Sosnica Corridor III 120,00 84,21<br />

Reconstruction A4 Highway Krzyzowa - Wroclaw * Corridor III 374,00 189,53<br />

11.5 Axle Load Strenghthening on National Roads Corridors I,II, III, VI 496,00 62,12<br />

11.5 Axle Load A4 Highway and Nat'l Road No. 4 Corridor III & Add. 46,67<br />

11.5 Axle Load Nat'l Road No. 717 Corridor II 24,57<br />

Project Management Training of Staff N/A 0,40<br />

Pre-Feasibility Study Warsaw Transport Node Corridors I,II & VI 0,71<br />

Kwiatkowski access route to seaport of Gdynia Corridor VI 47,00<br />

Construction Nat'l Road No.1 Skoczow-Ciezyn Corridor VI 47,00<br />

Modernization Nat'l Road S 18 Wyszkow * Corridor I 80,00<br />

Construction Nat'l Road No.1 Bielsko-Skoczow Corridor VI 38,00<br />

Construction A4 Highway Zgorzelec - Krzyzowa * Corridor III 285,00<br />

Road Access to port of Gdansk Corridor VI 71,00<br />

Modernization S-94 National Road Zywiec-Zwardon Corridor VI 97,00<br />

PERCENTAGE OF GRANTS ROAD SECTOR 60% 54%<br />

* = Listed in National Strategy as 2 Projects Total 2741,00 752,00<br />

Source: Own compilation using data from the European Commission DG Regional<br />

Policy ISPA Website (http://europa.eu.int/comm/regional_policy/funds/ispa/ispa_en.htm)<br />

and the National ISPA Transport Strategy Poland


340<br />

The table shows that the projects submitted exclusively concern the road and rail<br />

sectors, with 20% more road than rail submissions. Actual grants until 2001, however,<br />

displayed a more even modal distribution. So far, the granting of Polish transport grants<br />

seems to have progressed rather closely according to the list submitted with the National<br />

Strategy. Also, Commission officials commented on the comparatively high capacity of<br />

the Polish counterparts to adequately manage and absorb the funds, a circumstance that<br />

was not given for all the candidate countries.<br />

8.4.3 Preliminary Conclusions: EU ISPA Grants for Poland (2000-2001)<br />

In 2000, as part of its National ISPA Transport Strategy, Poland submitted a “List of<br />

proposals of investment projects for ISPA co-financing” which contained 19 projects<br />

totaling € 2742 million. Of this, € 1655 million were for road and € 1086 million for rail<br />

projects. This total project volume was more than twice as high as Poland’s maximum<br />

ISPA allowance of € 1344 million (i.e. the added yearly possible maximum of € 174<br />

million from 2000-2006), so that the Commission still had significant leeway in<br />

concentrating investments in particular modes or locales. Additionally, as noted above,<br />

Commission officials had already made it clear to their Polish counterparts that they<br />

believed all Polish ISPA projects should be located on Helsinki corridors. Within the<br />

larger array of possible large-scale infrastructure projects that were then submitted as<br />

eligible grants projects, responsible Commission officials further steered the prioritization<br />

process towards a select number of projects located in Helsinki corridors, mostly those<br />

close to the Western borders (Germany). The TINA exercise was decidedly not used as<br />

an input for project prioritization in the Regional Policy Directorate. By the end of 2001,<br />

projects in the amount of € 752 million had been approved by the ISPA Management


341<br />

Committee, i.e. well over half of the maximum ISPA transport grant volume to Poland<br />

(or 62% of the mean total volume foreseen). Almost all of the projects approved so far<br />

are international rail lines and expressways in Helsinki Corridors II and III. Interestingly,<br />

there is one significant “joker” in the Polish ISPA list that has presented an important<br />

counterweight to the strongly west-oriented expressway bias in road sector grant<br />

allocations, and that is the axle load strengthening program. At € 496 million this “group<br />

of projects” accounts for 30% of the entire road sector submissions. This final item on<br />

the Polish ISPA projects list essentially presents a back door for funding all those<br />

national roads that are part of the entire TINA network but which are not expressways on<br />

the primary axes of the corridors. Many of these national roads run roughly parallel to<br />

the planned future expressways foreseen as the final Helsinki corridor backbones, and<br />

many carry increasingly heavy transit traffic. Some, however, are not congruent with the<br />

expressway alignments. Note that a similar “joker” does not exist for the rail sector, so<br />

that the bias for international transit lines is more pronounced. As far as the location of<br />

the rail sector allocations is concerned, however, there is less of a “western” bias in the<br />

allocations. As far as the balance between modes is concerned, there seems to have been<br />

a conscious effort by both the Commission and the Polish counterparts to keep<br />

allocations evenly balanced between the road and rail sector. Overall, the Polish ISPA<br />

grant allocations appear as a relatively well-crafted, carefully worked out compromise<br />

that displays a predictable prioritization of East-West oriented international transit<br />

corridors.


342<br />

8.5 EU ISPA Transport Funding for Hungary<br />

8.5.1 The National Context: Hungarian Transport Policy (Post- Transition)<br />

Any scholar researching transport issues in Hungary is quickly enlightened about<br />

several idiosyncracies of the Hungarian infrastructure network. Most importantly,<br />

contrary to the polycentric settlement structure predominant in Poland, Hungary’s urban<br />

system is extremely dominated by Budapest. With 1,8 million inhabitants, Budapest is<br />

clearly Hungary’s primate city. Although two thirds of Hungary’s population is urban,<br />

the majority live in towns of less than 40,000 inhabitants, and only a few secondary cities<br />

approach 100,000 in size. The reasons are of course largely historical. 24 Consequently,<br />

the transport network is extremely centralized, with Budapest functioning as its main<br />

bottleneck for anyone wishing to travel from one end of the country to the other. This is<br />

particularly true for the rail sector. Ninety percent of the entire bridge lane capacity<br />

(including public transport links) across the Danube are located in Budapest, only two<br />

other major crossings exit.<br />

As in many communist countries, serious backlogs in rehabilitation maintenance<br />

were build up during the 1980s when the Hungarian economy went through recession.<br />

Ambitious road building programs were postponed and even basic maintenance was<br />

neglected in the rail sector, whose infrastructure had been extended significantly in<br />

previous decades. Despite the faltering economy, there was already a continuous, albeit<br />

24 During the 19 th century, Hungary was trying to assert its independence from the Austrian empire, and<br />

thus built up Budapest as a strong alternative capital. At this time, Hungary was about three times as large<br />

as it is now, and important secondary cities of the former empire like Bratislava or Zagreb are now located<br />

in neighboring countries. Although the country’s first comprehensive transport infrastructure plan,<br />

developed by Count Szechenyi in 1848 envisaged a comprehensive network that also directly connected<br />

outlying regions though peripheral and lateral connections, this plan was never fully implemented. Instead,<br />

a more radial system concentrating on the capital was developed after the loss of was parts of the country’s<br />

territories after the first World War. After the Second World War, Communist leaders found this radial<br />

infrastructure to be suited to the needs of their centralized economy.


343<br />

moderate increase in private vehicle ownership in Hungary during the 1980s. The other<br />

decisive trend – similar to other transition economies, albeit somewhat earlier than<br />

elsewhere – was the continued changeover from rail-based to road-based, increasingly<br />

small trucking-dominated transport in the freight sector. Figure 8.3 illustrates this<br />

development, which together with the continued parallel rise in private vehicle<br />

ownership, led to increasing political pressure for highway expansion.<br />

As early as 1992, the Hungarian government adopted the so-called “principles of<br />

the Hungarian transport policy.” From these, four strategic directions were developed,<br />

which are considered “of equal importance” and elaborated further in the official<br />

Hungarian Transport Policy adopted in 1996 (KÖVIM 1996):<br />

- Promotion of integration into the European Union<br />

- Enhancement of the conditions of co-operation with the neighboring<br />

countries, and of a more balanced regional development of the country,<br />

- Protection of human life and of the environment, and<br />

- Effective, market-oriented transport regulations<br />

Figure 8.3 The Rise of Road-Based Freight Transport in Hungary (1980-1994)<br />

Change in Modal Split<br />

for Hungarian Freight Transport<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

1980 1985 1990 1994<br />

Road (including Small Truckers)<br />

Small Truckers<br />

Rail<br />

Inland Waterways*<br />

Pipelines<br />

* From 1993 numbers are inconsistent<br />

due to exclusion of deep sea shipping<br />

Data Source: Ministry of Transport (1996, Appendix, Table 4)


344<br />

These strategic directions are consistent with an overall eco-modernist agenda.<br />

More importantly, the official Hungarian policy explicitly voices a strong Keynesian<br />

belief that investments in transport are the best way to stimulate development, i.e. it<br />

clearly adheres to the (academically disputed) public capital hypothesis formulated by<br />

Aschauer and others (also see Chapter 2) which strongly emphasizes macroeconomic<br />

spillover-effects from transport infrastructure investments. At the same time, the policy<br />

makes a clear reference to EU cohesion countries as models for Hungarian development,<br />

thus implicitly also making an investment-for-cohesion argument (for details on the<br />

“cohesion” storyline, see Chapter 6). The respective passage in the policy is worth<br />

quoting in its entirety (KÖVIM 1996:13-14):<br />

[In countries like] Spain, Portugal, Greece, the development of transportation, while<br />

also anticipatory, acted as leading force, for the other sectors of the economy.<br />

Development programs in transportation which purposefully preceded other sectors of<br />

development, started with good reason. The aim was to create favourable conditions<br />

for capital and resource input, particularly for those that originate abroad. For<br />

Hungary, due to its present economic state and desirable future growth path, the lesson<br />

of [such] countries at a mid-level of development (which also are “catching up” fast)<br />

has more to offer than that of the most developed ones. Another favourable impact of<br />

transportation development is through the multiplier effect, the results of which on the<br />

economy as a whole is proven by international research. According to this, each unit<br />

of investment made in transportation development generates, in the country or in a<br />

particular territory, 2.5-3 times its size, in private investment. Transportation<br />

development, in terms of its overall impact on the economy, is second only behind<br />

telecommunications and is ahead of all other sectors. Moreover, at a macro economic<br />

level, at times of recession, a well thought-out development program in transportation<br />

is capable of filling the role of a counter-cyclic agent.<br />

The “strategic directions” section also has a clearly Keynesian slant (p.21):<br />

Investments in infrastructure act as stimulants in economic policy aimed at a program<br />

of structural transformation, and as such, they should be initiated, supported and<br />

funded by the state. One of the prerequisites of a renewed growth in production is an<br />

infrastructure oriented development program.


345<br />

As far as mode specific details relating to the first strategic direction, i.e. the<br />

promotion of EU integration is concerned, the Hungarian national policy clearly favors<br />

investments in the road sector. Interestingly, the 1996 does not [yet] pre-dominantly<br />

focus on new construction, but emphasizes maintenance, and even mentions cycle paths<br />

as an element promoting EU integration. Bypass roads, however, are also mentioned,<br />

thereby implicitly reemphasizing the importance of the M0 ring road as an “EU<br />

integration project”:<br />

Previously postponed programs of maintenance in the road network must be carried<br />

out without delay. The program should, later on [sic] include the completion of<br />

autostradas [motorways] in the transit corridors … as well as … new bridges.<br />

Additional general programs include building of bypass roads, reduction … of the<br />

number of road/railway level crossings, reconstruction of points with high traffic<br />

concentration, at peripheral locations, and expansion of the bicycle path network.<br />

Within the railway network, only selective developments can be envisaged. These<br />

will include, primarily, modernisation of the main transit lines, investments in areas<br />

wherever cost reduction and/or quality improvement can be achieved, and where<br />

safety will be enhanced.<br />

[bold italics in the original, additional bold emphases added]<br />

In other sections, the document also contains rather specific statements regarding<br />

various mode-specific developments as well as the relationship between maintenance and<br />

new construction. However, in contrast to Keynesian-type approaches favoring reliance<br />

on large-scale public works, the 1996 Transport Policy estimates that only about one<br />

quarter of the total estimated financial resource requirements for all modes, namely 680<br />

to 770 billion HUF, i.e. over € 2 billion would have to be covered by the state.<br />

Nevertheless, the official document makes no direct reference to the most contested<br />

Hungarian transport initiative of the time, i.e. the toll road concessions for the M1/15 and<br />

the M5 motorways. Given the government’s acute lack of financial resources, toll roads<br />

were regarded by many experts as the best way to complete missing sections of the


346<br />

national highway network. As it turned out, the government’s hopes of being able to<br />

speed-up highway construction through private-sector funded, build-operate-transfer<br />

(BOT) concessions were ultimately gravely disappointed due to major problems with the<br />

actual concession schemes. The M1/M15 concession disaster still serves as warning<br />

example for other CEE governments. 25<br />

As far as public reactions to the official Transport Policy were concerned, the<br />

document received the predictable kudos from the infrastructure and construction sector<br />

and the equally predictable criticism from environmental organizations and railway<br />

enthusiasts (see e.g. Clean Air Action Group and Hungarian Traffic Club 1999).<br />

The 1996 document is still considered the official Hungarian Transport Policy. 26<br />

However, there have been major changes in Hungarian transport policy since 1996,<br />

particularly in the wake of the 1998 and the 2002 national elections. Most importantly,<br />

the first National ISPA Strategy for Hungary had to be prepared at a time when the<br />

country was in the midst of political restructuring. Consequently, the preparations of the<br />

25 During an ECMT expert seminar, KÖVIM representative Ferenc Szabó and EBRD representative Dr.<br />

Andras Timar presented comparatively sympathetic accounts of the experience. Yet even they admit that<br />

tolling motorways remains “a very sensitive issue” (Szabó 1999) and that under prevailing conditions in<br />

Central Europe, the opportunity costs of the necessary substantial government contributions must be<br />

thoroughly evaluated (Timár 1999:6). Meanwhile, Hook (1999:212) presents a much more outspoken<br />

critique of the highly problematic M1 toll concession, which lost millions of Euros and eventually lead to a<br />

costly government bailout operation at taxpayers’ expense. As he summarizes:<br />

After the M1 was built, traffic and revenues were 50% below projections, mainly because most<br />

Hungarian motorists elected to take slower, parallel untolled routes. … Unable to meet its debt<br />

payments, in June of 1999 ELMKA [the concession company] was taken over by the Hungarian<br />

Government. All of ELMKA’s assets were turned over to a fully-state owned ‘Replacement Company.’<br />

Most of the initial investors lost their [substantial] equity investments. … The consortium of banks that<br />

lent money to the concession company also lost US$31 million. [Yet] in the end the road will cost the<br />

Government of Hungary some US$30 million less than if they had simply built the road as a public toll<br />

road with EBRD loans. As a result of the experience, the EBRD’s new transport policy states that it will<br />

only get involved in BOT highway projects in the future where the level of government subsidies to the<br />

project are much greater or where the concessionaire’s rate of return is guaranteed by the<br />

government…. This position fits uncomfortably with the EBRD’s policy of working to remove<br />

subsidies in the public transit and rail sectors.<br />

26 An English language version remains available for download on the website of the newly formed the<br />

Ministry of Economy and Transportation (via the still-existing website of its legal predecessor). See<br />

www.kovim.hu/Celok/Kozlekedes/EU-Integration/Transport_policy/Transport_policy_of_Hungary.doc


347<br />

Hungarian National ISPA Strategy documents were intimately related with the release of<br />

the new government’s national economic development plan (“Széchenyi Plan”). This<br />

document deserves some detailed attention. In particular, a closer look at the<br />

government’s Széchenyi Plan will explain why the initial draft ISPA Transport Sector<br />

Strategy of June 1999 (prepared by the Hungarian Transport Ministry) was completely<br />

changed and a totally different ISPA priority list presented to the EU about a year later.<br />

In 1998, national elections were then won by the center-right parties, 27<br />

who<br />

agreed that the national motorway program should be accelerated, but who had their own,<br />

very particular ideas about how the construction program should be financed. In 1999,<br />

the new coalition government under Prime Minister Victor Orbán adopted a ten-year<br />

motorway expressway program which was accelerated to seven years in 2000. In the<br />

spring of 2000, the Economic Ministry then presented a national economic development<br />

plan, the so-called Széchenyi Plan (GM 2000). One of the cornerstones of the Plan was<br />

an ambitious expressway construction program which in turn was centered around an<br />

immediate expansion of the M3 and M7 highways (to be completed until the end of<br />

2002) as well as the construction of the Szekszárd Danube bridge (until mid-2003).<br />

Additionally, the plan also proposed the modernization of three railway lines along key<br />

Helsinki corridors along Zalaegerszeg-Boda, Budapest-Cegléd-Szolno-Lökösháza and<br />

Budapest-Hegyshalom as well as a regional airport development subprogram. Tables 8.3<br />

and 8.4 list the proposed measures in the new seven year plan.<br />

27 The new government was formed on July 8, 1998 by three parties: the Fidesz Hungarian Civic Party<br />

(Fidesz-MPP), the Independent Smallholder's Party (FKgP) and the Hungarian Democratic Forum (MDF).


348<br />

According to the Széchenyi Plan’s own rhetoric, the program appeared firmly set<br />

within a framework of market-oriented economic modernization that adhered to EU<br />

framework priorities:<br />

The Széchenyi Plan is a program for rapid and sustainable economic<br />

development. The fundamental objective of the Széchenyi Plan is to provide for<br />

dynamic and sustainable economic growth and to improve the Hungarian economy’s<br />

level of competitiveness. [See Section 5].<br />

The Széchenyi Plan introduces a planning practice that is radically new in Hungary.<br />

This practice rests on three major aspects: partnership between the government and the<br />

business sector; limited co-financing by the government; and program financing for a<br />

coordinated use of government supports. … The Széchenyi Plan remains firmly and<br />

purely on a market economic footing. This is a program financing in the manner<br />

practiced in the European Union…. Even though the word “plan” is included in the<br />

title of the Széchenyi Plan, it is, naturally, completely different from the planning<br />

practices of the past forty years in Hungary.<br />

[Section 6, emphasis added].<br />

Table 8.3 The Széchenyi Plan’s Railway Modernization Program<br />

Source: Hungarian Ministry of the Economy (GM 2000)


349<br />

Table 8.4 The Széchenyi Plan’s Expressway Construction Program<br />

Source: Hungarian Ministry of the Economy (GM 2000)


350<br />

Most importantly, the Széchenyi Plan completely redefined the role of the state<br />

and other players in expressway development. The Plan directly critiqued the previous<br />

government’s concession-oriented approach as “extremely costly both for the state and<br />

motorists.” However, instead of using the opportunity to open a debate over more<br />

socially just, economically acceptable, and financially viable (i.e. “sustainable”) ways of<br />

approaching the expansion of the national highway network, the new Orbán government<br />

did exactly the opposite. Echoing the protectionist, and in part nationalist, interests<br />

represented by the various coalition parties, the Széchenyi Plan argued that the previous<br />

concessional solution had resulted in an unfavorable situation where foreign companies<br />

dominated the expressway construction market and that priorities therefore had to be<br />

arranged according to the following four goals:<br />

to build expressways faster and at a smaller investment cost than before;<br />

to make the use of expressways financially viable for motorists;<br />

to allow Hungarian financial institutions and personal savings to play a greater role in<br />

financing the developments;<br />

and to allow Hungarian road companies to play a greater role in the execution of<br />

developments<br />

(GM 2000).<br />

What followed in the next two years, however, was neither cost and time efficient<br />

nor in sync with “market economic footing” but essentially a corruption scandal which is<br />

only now being investigated in detail. Following the publication of the Széchenyi Plan,<br />

the National Motorway Company Nemzeti Autópálya Rt. (NA), founded by the new<br />

government in 1999 via Government decision 2117/1999 and 99% owned by the stateowned<br />

Hungarian Development Bank, ignored all rules of public procurement legally<br />

required both according to EU and Hungarian law. No tenders were called for the


351<br />

construction contracts, and none of the three qualified Hungarian construction firms in<br />

possession of the appropriate equipment to carry out such large-scale road works were<br />

contacted by NA Rt. (Pócza 2000). Instead, two Hungarian construction companies who<br />

had never before been involved in motorway construction (and who were characterized as<br />

politically close to the governing Fidesz party in the national press, see e.g. Lovas 2000),<br />

Vegyépszer Rt. and Betonút Rt., were awarded both the first contract for the M3 and<br />

numerous subsequent ones.<br />

The circumstances of this contracting and funds<br />

disbursement process were highly dubious from the start, and even included sub-contracts<br />

with quarries owned by the family of the Prime Minister (ibid). 28<br />

Under these<br />

circumstances, EU Commission representatives made it clear to the Hungarian<br />

government that they could not realistically expect to receive any ISPA co-financing for<br />

their motorway construction program. As we will see, ISPA grant funding in Hungary<br />

was therefore heavily concentrated in the rail sector during the first two years.<br />

28 By the time that the Orbán government was ousted in the May 2002 elections, none of the motorways in<br />

the above listed table had been completed, and for many of them, work in fact had not even begun. In the<br />

end, allegations of corruption and incompetence related to the construction program were a significant<br />

factor in the 2002 elections. The opposition especially criticized the fact that financing the expressways via<br />

the Hungarian Development Bank (MFP) and not through the state budget meant that there was no<br />

parliamentary control over these expenses. In the weeks following the election, the new center-left socialdemocratic<br />

government formed by the MSZP and the SZDSZ and headed by Péter Medgyessy acted<br />

quickly. By late June 2002, the entire management and board of directors of NA Rt. had been exchanged,<br />

and the vast majority of the incoming representatives are now also members of the two governing parties.<br />

Similar measures were taken at the Hungarian Development Bank. In late July, the new government then<br />

even annulled a previous July 11 invitation-only tender (in which Vegyépszer Rt. had not been invited to<br />

take part) and promised open tenders for all subsequent contracts. In early August, the new CEO of the<br />

Hungarian Development Bank told the Hungarian press that the repayments of the credits taken out for the<br />

expressway construction projects might cost Hungarian taxpayers as much as HUF 180 billion (over € 730<br />

million) for want of cover on the part of the Hungarian Development Bank.


352<br />

8.5.2 The Hungarian ISPA Transport Strategies and their Priorities 29<br />

The initial 1999 draft ISPA National Transport Strategy document was very much<br />

a cut-and-paste document that did not undergo much final editing. Different sections<br />

even display different type fonts and sizes (and sometimes even colors). There is no table<br />

of contents. The entire document is separated (i.e. segmented) into an introductory part,<br />

and a road and a rail sector annex which sometimes repeat information and do not relate<br />

to each other. The draft does not [yet] contain any priority projects for inland navigation<br />

or civil aviation. Not surprisingly, the document was not well received in Brussels. On<br />

an editorial level, the responsible Brussels desk officers demanded a more coherent, more<br />

consistent document with a clearer argumentation leading to a logical set of ISPA priority<br />

projects. On a pragmatic level, the 1999 draft version listed priorities within the road and<br />

rail sectors, but did not allow for any prioritization between road, rail or other projects.<br />

Within the rail sector, however, the 1999 draft was already unproblematic. The three top<br />

ISPA priority projects were identical with the Széchenyi Plan priorities (see Table 8.4<br />

above). These were in turn identical with Helsinki corridors IV and V, so there was thus<br />

a mutual interest from the Hungarian and the EU sides to first modernize these lines.<br />

The road sector, however, was more problematic. In the 1999 draft, the “key<br />

projects forming part of the government strategy” are introduced as follows:<br />

29 Much unlike the Polish officials, Hungarian officials were extremely reluctant to provide me with inside<br />

insights into the gestation and formulation of the Hungarian ISPA strategy when I conducted my interviews<br />

in Budapest in August 2000. At that time, final consultations on the second, dramatically changed version<br />

of the strategy had not been completed, and the material was still highly politically sensitive. Contrary to<br />

the Polish case, I therefore was not able to conduct detailed, first-hand interviews with the actual author(s)<br />

of the ISPA strategy documents. As evident in this chapter, I still managed to obtain a significant amount<br />

of information, including copies of both the draft 1999 and the final 2000 versions of the Hungarian<br />

National ISPA Strategy, but this information did not come from official governmental channels. Note,<br />

however, that by 2002 (and possibly earlier) the final ISPA version could be found on the Transport<br />

Ministry’s website.


353<br />

There are thirteen [road sector] projects proposed to receive ISPA support within the<br />

coming medium term period. These projects from [sic] the 'long' list in the first etap<br />

[phase]. Most of these projects are situated in the Helsinki Corridor and belong to the<br />

TINA network. 4 projects from the 'long' list being able to start in 2000 have been put<br />

to the so-called 'short' list (4.1-4.4). After a site visit experts delegated by European<br />

Committee DG XVI [sic] suggested 2 of these 4 projects to form part of ISPA 2000.<br />

[These are:]<br />

1. Construction of Motorway M7 between Budapest and Zamárdi […]<br />

2. Construction of Motorway M3 between Füzesabony and Polgár<br />

So at least at this point, the top two ISPA road priorities were still fully congruent<br />

with the national development objectives in the Széchenyi Plan. EU delegates had also<br />

clearly identified these particular projects as top ISPA priorities. Of the additional eleven<br />

projects listed in the document, most of them were also congruent with the Széchenyi<br />

Plan priorities. In particular, of the listed ISPA priorities 3 through 7, only one project,<br />

the expressway M43, differed from the Széchenyi Plan priorities. All other projects<br />

listed, i.e. the Eastern section of the M0 ring road, the M30 between Emöd and Miskolc,<br />

the M7 between Zamárdi and Letenye and the M9 expressway bridge across the Danube<br />

at Szekszárd come straight from the Széchenyi Plan priority list.<br />

For reasons explained above, the final ISPA strategy document from June 2000<br />

then presents a very different picture. Challenged to explain the sudden withdrawl of<br />

almost all previous top road priorities from the final ISPA document, the Hungarian<br />

government chose to downplay this radical departure by pretending that only two projects<br />

were withdrawn. As the final ISPA Strategy has it:<br />

At the beginning of 2000 a new Government Decision was made (2037/2000) to<br />

speed-up the construction of new motorways. The Hungarian Development Bank Ltd.<br />

was entrusted with full responsibility for the financing of motorway and expressway<br />

development, and NA Rt. was requested to contract directly with Hungarian firms for<br />

the construction of priority motorway sections. As a result of this decision, two<br />

motorway projects which were previously considered for ISPA Funding, M7 and M3,<br />

were withdrawn from the list of potential ISPA projects.


354<br />

In reality, however, not only those two, but practically all other Széchenyi Plan<br />

priorities were also dropped from the new priority list. By then, the EU had obviously<br />

made it clear to their Hungarian counterparts that no EU co-financing would be given for<br />

construction projects that did not adhere to standard procurement rules. So in the end, the<br />

Hungarian government only listed three road sector priority projects in its final National<br />

ISPA Transport Strategy: a general axle load strengthening program along national roads,<br />

the section of the M43 between the M5 and the Romanian border and the Eastern section<br />

of the M0 highway. Additionally, an additional road project was “hidden” in the “inland<br />

navigation” ISPA priority list: the Hungarian government planned to request € 27.4<br />

million for the “construction for a new ‘spinal’ access road connection to the port of<br />

Csepel (Budapest) on the Danube” (p.23).<br />

The three rail sector priorities, by contrast, appear entirely unchanged, except that<br />

they are now listed before the road sector priorities. Finally, in addition to two new<br />

inland navigation projects, the Hungarian government now also requests ISPA grant<br />

funding for three civil aviation projects that did not previously appear in the ISPA draft.<br />

Table 8.5 presents an overview of the planned and received ISPA transport grants to<br />

Hungary.


355<br />

Table 8.5 Overview of ISPA Transport Grants to Hungary<br />

ISPA Transport Grants to Hungary TINA Planned Approved<br />

(in Million €) Location? ('00-'06) ('00-'01)<br />

Rehabilitation Railline Budapest-Györ-Hegeshalom Corridor IV 43,00 42,99<br />

Rehabilitation Railline Vecsés-Szolnok Corridor IV 63,00 63,00<br />

Rehabilitation Railline Zalalövö-Boba Corridor V 84,00 83,70<br />

Technical Assistance Railline Szolnok-Lökösháza Corridor IV 0,50 0,15<br />

Technical Assistance additional rail projects Corridors IV & V 1,50 1,61<br />

PERCENTAGE OF GRANTS RAIL SECTOR 50% 90%<br />

11.5 Axle Load Trunk Roads 3 and 35 Additional 34,00 20,00<br />

Technical Assistance 11.5 Axle Load Project Additional 0,50 0,15<br />

Expressway M0 Budapest (Eastern section) Corridor Node 71,50<br />

Expressway M43 (M5 – Romanian border) Corridor VI 26,50<br />

"Inland navigation": Access road Csepel port B'pest “TINA Riverport” 10,50<br />

Technical Assistance Expressways Misc. Corridors 0,50<br />

PERCENTAGE OF GRANTS ROAD SECTOR 38% 10%<br />

Multimodal cargo terminal Györ-Gönyü Danube port Corridor VIII 5,50<br />

Airport Budapest Ferchegy International TINA Airport 20,00<br />

Airport Debrecen Proposed Additions 10,00<br />

Airport Balaton Proposed Additions 10,00<br />

Technical Assistance Budapest Airport TINA Airport 0,50<br />

PERCENTAGE OF GRANTS MULTIMODAL & AIR 12% 0%<br />

Total 381,50 211,60<br />

Source: Own compilation using data from the European Commission, DG Regional<br />

Policy Website (http://europa.eu.int/comm/regional_policy/funds/ispa/ispa_en.htm) and<br />

the National ISPA Transport Strategy Poland<br />

8.5.3 Preliminary Conclusions: EU ISPA grants for Hungary (2000-2001)<br />

Between 1999 and 2001, ISPA transport grants were selected and approved under<br />

difficult political circumstances in Hungary. Deficiencies in road sector project<br />

accountability led to an originally unintended, almost exclusive concentration of ISPA<br />

funds in the rail sector. Contrary to Poland, the final project list in the June 2000 ISPA<br />

Strategy only listed a total project volume slightly in excess of Hungary’s maximum<br />

possible ISPA transport sector allocation (i.e. a total of € 381.5 million compared to a


356<br />

total possible of € 364 million). By the end of 2001, a total of € 191.49 million had been<br />

allocated to the rail sector, accounting for 90% of all allocations until that time, and<br />

already for 52% of the total possible, and for 63.3% of the mean allocated volume of<br />

ISPA transport grants to Hungary. Together with one non-expressway axle load<br />

strengthening project, these projects then accounted for 58% of the total possible, and<br />

70% of the mean allocated volume for Hungary. No funds were approved for either<br />

expressway development or access roads. Whether this record will be reversed in 2002<br />

after the post-election restructuring of the Hungarian motorway agency remains to be<br />

seen. 30 In Hungary, the EU encountered a situation where the Commission’s only last<br />

option to ensure transparency in the allocation of funds (i.e. procedural sustainability),<br />

namely to threaten to withhold grants for the road sector if international procurement<br />

rules were not met, was more or less shrugged off by the recipient government, which<br />

then decided to finance the respective highway sections on its own. One might argue that<br />

by still providing grant funds to the rail sector, the EU might have thus “freed up”<br />

additional governmental funds for the unaccountable road sector. However, choosing to<br />

also withhold funds from the struggling rail sector at a time where this mode continued to<br />

lose shares against road-based motorization also hardly seemed like a desirable choice.<br />

As far as the overall “sustainability” of the EU’s grant funding in Hungary is concerned,<br />

30 As far as medium- to long-term transport sector preferences of the new Hungarian government are<br />

concerned, they are not likely to be different from their predecessors. In their renewed ambitiousness, they<br />

clearly recall post-war German autobahn projects. As Benkö (2002) reported in mid-August 2002:<br />

Economy and Transport Minister István Csillag said [that] …. the proposals will be based on the<br />

previous government’s medium-term and long-term road building programs. “As part of the pan-<br />

European network, a primary goal of Hungary’s transport policy by 2015 is to build a freeway network<br />

from border to border, crossing the country from north to south and east to west, with a density that<br />

ensures access to the nearest motorway or principal road in half an hour from any point of the<br />

country,” reads the plan that the ministry will submit to the government. [Emphasis added]


357<br />

most of the more problematic choices, such as the decision over the eastern section of the<br />

M0 ring road or for civil aviation projects, have so far been postponed, so that it would be<br />

premature to pass judgment on the portfolio as it stood in late 2001.<br />

8.6 Concluding Remarks on the EU’s ISPA Transport Program<br />

It is still too early to present any strong conclusions on the EU’s new ISPA<br />

program. But based on ISPA program directives and requirements, as well as on the<br />

record of lending and grant making activity until December 2001, the following remarks<br />

can be offered:<br />

The ISPA National Strategies played and still play very different roles in the two<br />

case study countries in terms of re-organizing national transport policies. Disputes over<br />

the content of these strategies once again demonstrate the conflicted and contested nature<br />

of EU transport policy making, as well as its particular problems in the enlargement<br />

countries. The different documents were clearly written under very different political<br />

circumstances at the national level. It is interesting to note that Polish official(s)<br />

obviously took the writing of the ISPA national strategy document as a welcome<br />

opportunity to force their government to develop a medium to long-term, mode-specific<br />

list of priorities in the transport sector and to commit to a multi-year strategy (thereby<br />

making Polish transport policy more “sustainable” at least in the sense that it might<br />

become more future-oriented, internally consistent and better integrated across sectors).<br />

In Hungary, by contrast, the writing of the strategy was seen mostly as a necessary<br />

document to receive supplementary financial aid from Brussels. When it became clear<br />

that the grave violations of international procurement rules in the national expressway


358<br />

program would result in their road sector projects being rejected by the ISPA<br />

management committee, the Hungarian government simply rearranged their ISPA<br />

strategy and excluded the problematic motorways from the list.<br />

In the end, the fact that Hungarian ISPA funding record for the first two years was<br />

90% biased in favor of rail is a highly atypical, special case. More importantly, this ISPA<br />

grant-related imbalance in favor of rail has to be seen in the context of a continued bias in<br />

favor of road projects both in terms of national government funding and IFI loans. Since<br />

railway projects in CEE typically require a broader sectoral approach involving difficult<br />

questions of overall restructuring (including, in most cases, highly politically issues of<br />

downsizing and retraining due to overstaffing), and also since rail investments are<br />

frequently more complicated to justify in terms of strict financial and economic rates of<br />

return, there is always a danger of more international funding going to Helsinki road than<br />

rail corridors, thus further tipping the balance against more sustainable modes. So far,<br />

however, ISPA allocations have been rather evenly balanced between the road and the<br />

rail sectors, with over half of all grants going to rail projects. 31<br />

The European Union will continue to be the major grant financer of transport<br />

infrastructure in Central Eastern Europe. Since this grant funding will typically be used<br />

to leverage additional international funds, this money is likely to have a major influence<br />

on the future concentration of resources in the transport sector in CEE accession<br />

countries, also with regard to the use of IFI loans. The planned progressive<br />

decentralization of the ISPA program means that the CEEC themselves should have<br />

increasing control over the use of the funds, which in turn means that it will be more and<br />

31 Until December 31, 2001, modal allocations for all CEECs were 50.74% for rail, 46.99% for road, 0.21%<br />

for road and rail combined and 2.06% for airports. Also see CEC (2002d).


359<br />

more up to the CEEC to make sure that funds are used in the most environmentally<br />

friendly and regionally balanced manner. Presently, however, program decisions seem to<br />

still be rather strongly influenced by the EU’s DG Regio. At least in the case of the two<br />

countries more closely analyzed in this paper, DG Regio placed a near exclusive<br />

emphasis on funding major corridors facing the EU borders and was reluctant to consider<br />

non-Helsinki corridor TINA network stretches for initial funding.<br />

To be sure, the EU’s preference for funding a select number of international<br />

corridors which will better connect the candidate countries with the EU is of course<br />

hardly surprising and quite understandable from a larger perspective of European<br />

integration. What is at issue, however, is that the stated objective of ISPA is supposedly<br />

not to just to promote European integration by improving international road and rail<br />

connections, but rather “provide assistance … in the area of economic and social<br />

cohesion and for “transport infrastructure measures which promote sustainable mobility”<br />

(see above). Given the above analysis, this larger claims seem less justified and even a<br />

bit hypocritical, at least from a more locally-focused CEE perspective. This has also<br />

been pointed out by key experts both in Brussels and in the recipient countries. For<br />

example, in reacting to the launch of the Commission’s ISPA program, a CEPS Working<br />

Party report (1999:9) noted the following:<br />

Urban and regional transport are key elements in economic development,<br />

underpinning the service economy and labour markets. They also help to shape spatial<br />

development in and around cities for decades to come. Defining the "European"<br />

interest exclusively in terms of cross-border links neglects the other "European"<br />

dimensions: sustainable transport on the one hand, and (local) economic development<br />

on the other.<br />

As of October 1999, it was declared policy of ISPA – the regional aid forrunner [sic]<br />

for the candidate countries – to limit grant aid to the Trans European Network. This is<br />

a major policy error to be addressed by the new Directorate General for Enlargement<br />

and the equally new joint DG for environment [sic - energy] and transport.


360<br />

This view is also partially shared by Prof. Wojciech Suchorzewski, Poland’s<br />

leading international transport policy expert. Invited to deliver the keynote presentation<br />

at the ECMT’s 2001 Transport Policy Forum, he presented the following assessment<br />

which confirms and re-summarizes the key conclusions from this ISPA case study<br />

chapter (European Conference of Ministers of Transport (ECMT) 2001:13):<br />

In several cases this focus [on Pan-European transport corridors] is well justified by<br />

the intensity of both international and national traffic/transport. However, there are<br />

areas of networks not belonging to trans-European corridors where the volumes of<br />

regional/national traffic may be much higher than in these corridors. … Allocation of<br />

large amount [sic] of money (through EIB, PHARE/ISPA etc) to projects on Pan-<br />

European corridors may, to some extent, reduce investments into other national or<br />

regional roads and railways, in spite of the fact that their importance for the whole<br />

network might be comparable or even higher than links belonging to international<br />

corridors. Deterioration of local/suburban railway systems serving large cities and<br />

agglomerations is among the least desirable results. And the backlog in road<br />

maintenance and rehabilitation of secondary networks may be growing.<br />

In sum, we can hardly answer the question of how “sustainable” EU transport<br />

infrastructure investments in Central Eastern Europe are without first considering the<br />

spatial scale at which we are making our argument. The spatial dimension cross-cuts our<br />

categorization of sustainable transport discourses, particularly with regard to<br />

modernization-oriented arguments. Taking the example of the Budapest ring road, the<br />

following chapter will therefore develop a typology of investment rationales that more<br />

explicitly distinguishes the different spatial scales at which sustainability arguments are<br />

being made. By way of transition, it is useful to re-consider the categorizations of<br />

sustainable transport discourses presented in Chapter 3 and 4. Here, the following<br />

remarks can be offered with regard to the issues discussed in this Chapter:<br />

“Renunciation”-type, eco-centric arguments are generally directed against all large-scale


361<br />

new infrastructures, regardless of whether they are national or international. “Political<br />

economy” arguments are less categorical. They make the “who benefits” question their<br />

central focus. Yet depending on whether the arguments are made from a primarily urban<br />

or rural, or a primarily national or local perspective, either backbone or secondary<br />

infrastructure investments might be favored. “Communicative rationality” approaches,<br />

by contrast, would put this process of normative preference setting (e.g. local vs.<br />

international preferences) center stage, and rather than take a stand in it beforehand, open<br />

it up for debate. They would certainly also insist on clear and transparent financing<br />

procedures. Finally, much like political economy approaches, “reflexive modernization”<br />

and “ecological modernization” approaches also privilege particular types of investments<br />

over others. Quite predictably, EU-approaches favor an accession-oriented focus on<br />

international links without necessarily relying on existing traffic flows or current market<br />

demand. Yet even rather mainstream academic (NGO) sources in Brussels (e.g. CEPS)<br />

as well as key experts in the EU and the CEEC are worried that the exclusive focus on<br />

international links is misguided. At the same time, more conformist, accession-oriented<br />

CEE government representatives work to rearrange national governmental perspectives in<br />

light of EU demands in order to extract maximum financing from EU and other<br />

international sources.


362<br />

Printed Thursday, October 31, 2002<br />

Last amended on September 17, 2002<br />

CHAPTER 9<br />

Local Dimensions of Sustainability:<br />

A Case Study of the Budapest Ring Road M0<br />

9.1 Introduction: The Significance of the M0 Case Study.................................... 363<br />

9.2 Description of the M0 Including a Chronology of International Funding...... 364<br />

9.2.1 The Southern Section: An undisputed fait accompli?............................. 366<br />

9.2.2 The Northern Section: A heavily disputed fait accompli........................ 367<br />

9.2.3 The Eastern Section: A comparatively undisputed fait non-accompli?.. 368<br />

9.2.4 The Western Section and the M0 Bridge: New priorities from 2002..... 369<br />

9.3 Arguments For and Against the M0 Ring Road: A Typology........................ 370<br />

9.4 Local and International Protests Against the Northern Section of the M0..... 375<br />

9.5 Risk-rational Concerns: Is Brussels Co-financing Urban Sprawl in Budapest? 381<br />

9.5.5 Reexamining the impact of ring roads on travel & land use................... 383<br />

9.5.6 The role of the M0 in spurring ex-urban development in Budapest ....... 387<br />

9.5.7 The lack of integrated transport and land use decision-making ............. 392<br />

9.5.8 The EU as a partial accomplice in a problematic transformation........... 396<br />

9.6 Conclusions..................................................................................................... 397


363<br />

9.1 Introduction: The Significance of the M0 Case Study<br />

This chapter looks at the financing of the Budapest ring road M0 as an instructive<br />

case study of how international, national, regional and local transport and land use policy<br />

interests interact, and to how they sometimes complement each other, sometimes conflict.<br />

Much like general environmental discourses around European transport policy, the M0<br />

“case” really consists of multiple discourses. Different spatial contexts result in different<br />

sustainability discourses. And as always, different discursive frameworks privilege<br />

different sets of arguments. In this chapter, I will apply my developed typology of<br />

discursive frameworks for “sustainable” transport policy decision-making to a concrete<br />

case study and compare how the overarching themes, key concepts and policy proposals<br />

of the five different discursive frameworks are reflected in the local controversies over a<br />

large-scale infrastructure. We will also re-identify our two key pro-construction<br />

rationales from Chapter 6, namely the “missing links” storyline which justifies the<br />

Budapest ring road as a part of the Pan-European transport networks, and also the locallevel<br />

“bottleneck” storyline which demands road infrastructure expansion due to rising<br />

traffic levels. 1<br />

However, as I will demonstrate below, these two storylines do not<br />

adequately capture the diversity of arguments for and against this key international link.<br />

The M0 case study is the only chapter in the “realities” part of this study that<br />

explicitly aims to take account of the actual effects of large-scale infrastructures at the<br />

local level. Due to the predominantly discourse-analytical focus of this study, this is a<br />

dimension which we have not closely investigated so far, but which we will pay<br />

1 Interestingly, the cohesion and polycentricity storylines are less suitable for justifying the ring road, since<br />

these storylines mostly stress parity of access and balanced urbanization at a national/international (rather<br />

than at a metropolitan) scale, meaning that the related arguments would necessarily tend to dissuade rather<br />

than encourage a concentration of additional infrastructure capacity in the already privileged, highly<br />

urbanized capital region of Hungary (also see discussions below).


364<br />

increasing attention to while addressing the sixth and last proposition of this study in<br />

more detail, namely the “Local Impacts” proposition. According to this proposition, the<br />

“ecological modernization” investment rationales favored by the EU tend to<br />

underestimate the negative local impacts of large-scale infrastructures. I will show how<br />

each of the other four discursive frameworks adds an important dimension to the overall<br />

issue. As we will see, not all of them can be adequately addressed within the current<br />

decision-making system.<br />

9.2 Description of the M0 Including a Chronology of International Funding<br />

The planned circular motorway around Budapest, the so-called M0, constitutes a<br />

key node in the Trans-European Networks. Four of the ten TEN corridors pass through<br />

Hungary, and all four of them intersect in the Budapest area, with one of them, the river<br />

Danube, passing right through the very center of the city. The exact bypass locations of<br />

the other corridors were not precisely defined at the time that the Helsinki corridors were<br />

decided upon (see figures 7.1, 7.4, 7.5, 7.7, and especially 7.11-7.13). The M0 is to<br />

connect the eastern motorways M1 from Vienna/Bratislava (Corridor IV) and the M7<br />

from Lake Balaton (Corridor V/Vb) with the M5 (Corridor IV) and the (currently nonexisting)<br />

M6 going South to the Former Yugoslavia and Romania (Corridor Vc) as well<br />

as the M3 going east to the Ukrainian border (continuation Corridor V) and the M2 going<br />

North. Figure 9.1 shows how the M0 connects to the major arteries of the city. Note that<br />

the 1998 base map does not show any alignment for last section in the West. This section<br />

of the M0 was neither part of TINA nor of the Hungarian government’s long-term<br />

motorway plan (also compare figures 7.11 and 7.13). Nevertheless, there are now


365<br />

reinvigorated calls to build this section sooner than originally planned. More specifically,<br />

the new socialist government is now calling the Northern M0 bridge and the completion<br />

of the ring a new national-level infrastructure priority.<br />

Figure 9.1: The Budapest Ring Road M0<br />

M2<br />

M0 New Danube Bridge &<br />

Western Sections?<br />

(was not a TINA or National Priority)<br />

M0 Northern<br />

Section<br />

(now completed)<br />

M3<br />

City Limits<br />

City Center<br />

M0 Eastern<br />

Section<br />

(planned)<br />

M1/M7<br />

City Limits<br />

M0 Southern Section (existing)<br />

M5<br />

Source A: Scanned Topograph AGAT map (1998) with own additions<br />

Source B: HVB Expertise (2001)


366<br />

9.2.1 The Southern Section: An undisputed fait accompli?<br />

In the early 1990s, the Hungarian government’s first step was to build the<br />

Southern section of the ring road in order to connect the M1 arriving from Vienna in the<br />

West with the M7 running South-West and with the M5 running South-East out of<br />

Budapest. These sections have been completed, in part with EBRD and World Bank<br />

money. 2<br />

The construction of this section was uncontroversial at the time, since its main<br />

purpose was to successfully route the vast majority of the unwanted East-West transit<br />

traffic around Budapest. Even the typically skeptical environmental NGOs noted that<br />

“remaining transit truck traffic [now] represents less than 2% of the traffic on the streets<br />

of Budapest [and] environmental groups did not oppose the construction of the Southern<br />

section of the M0 for this reason” (Mihok 1998). Note however, that these same groups<br />

have since grown rather disenchanted with this Southern section, mostly due to the<br />

mushrooming of greenfield developments along the M0 which they claim “created a<br />

much more serious traffic problem than the ring road was supposed to solve” (ibid). Also<br />

see discussions below. NGOs are thus likely to oppose the further expansion of this<br />

section from a limited access 2x2 highway into a 2x3 highway which is planned for the<br />

upcoming years.<br />

2 World Bank funds to the first section of the M0 were provided under their First Transport Project to<br />

Hungary (Loan Nr. 2557-HU), providing USD 30 million out of a total project cost of USD 75 million.<br />

Besides funding the M0, this loan also provided assistance to the Hungarian State Railways (MÁV) and the<br />

trucking company Hungarocamion. The loan was already approved in 1985, but the projects were only<br />

completed in 1992. In 1992, the EBRD provided a € 21 million loan to Hungary specifically for the M0.


367<br />

9.2.2 The Northern Section: A heavily disputed fait accompli<br />

The second section on the priority list was the controversial Northern section<br />

around Dunakezi which was to connect the old national road No. 2 and the new M2<br />

highway - both running straight north – with the M3 highway starting in the North of<br />

Budapest and running West. This section was completed in 1999, albeit with certain<br />

amendments and under strong protests from citizen and environmental groups. Further<br />

details of this controversial section are discussed in section 9.4. The project received cofunding<br />

through a € 72 million loan from the EIB and a € 14.26 million grant from the<br />

EU Phare program. 3<br />

In the respective Phare project evaluation fiche, the objective of the<br />

EU intervention is described as follows:<br />

The project purpose is to construct by-passes of the National Road No. 2, parts of the<br />

M0 (ring road of Budapest) motorway and interchanges to M3 (which leads to the<br />

center of Budapest) motorway and to the local network (old No. 2 national road). The<br />

projects contributes to the following overall Phare objective: To ensure a balance<br />

[sic] development of and between national roads, feeder and trunk roads and<br />

international links which constitute transit corridors and paths for external trade.<br />

[Emphasis added]<br />

This justification is interesting, since rather than just transit corridors in the<br />

classic sense (i.e. roads that carry a dominant share of non-local users), the EU here also<br />

purports to fund the more general development of a “balanced system” of different types<br />

of roads, including feeder roads to international corridors and trunk roads, thus harkening<br />

back to “cohesion”/“polycentricity” arguments rather than “missing-links”/“bottleneck”<br />

arguments. Of course, the EU Phare program would only contribute to a balanced<br />

development by funding this privileged link if (additional international) funding for other<br />

3 For additional information on the EU Phare program see Chapter 7.


368<br />

classes of roads were equally available (which has not necessarily been the case, also see<br />

Annex I). From a discourse analytical point of view, the cited Phare regional<br />

development objective represents an interesting “rationalization” for infrastructure<br />

funding, since it is conveniently phrased such that it in fact leaves the door wide open for<br />

funding almost any kind of road not strictly intended for local use. Keep in mind,<br />

however, that at least the main “victims” of the M0 ring road are likely to be found at the<br />

local level.<br />

The second source of EU-related funds came via the house bank of the EU, the<br />

EIB. Approved in 1993, the € 72 million EIB loan had two components: rehabilitation of<br />

350 km of existing roads as well as construction of a 35 km section of the M2 highway<br />

north of Budapest, part of which is included in the M0 ring road. The EIB also partially<br />

funded the new construction of national road Nr.2 to which the M0 was to connect.<br />

9.2.3 The Eastern Section: A comparatively undisputed fait non-accompli?<br />

The next major stretch to be built is the Eastern section. Hungary’s National<br />

ISPA strategy asked for EU funding for the new construction of the 46 km long stretch of<br />

the M0 ring road connecting the M3 and the M5 highways. The total budget of the<br />

project is a whopping € 469.5 million (1999 price level estimate, excluded VAT). The<br />

justification was as follows (Republic of Hungary 2000:21-22):<br />

The so-called “Eastern Sector” of the M0 Ring Road, functioning as bypass road to<br />

Budapest, starts at Motorway M5 and terminates at Motorway M3. This Section of the<br />

Budapest Ring Road forms part of the transit routes of south-west/north-east<br />

direction and forms link with the existing section to Motorways M1 and M7 (Pan-<br />

European Corridor V. and link to Corridor IV.). The construction of this major section<br />

of M0 will facilitate the development of traffic and result in very important gains in<br />

terms of time and safety for all kinds of passenger and freight road traffic (local,<br />

international and transit) in, out and through Budapest. It will substantially improve


369<br />

the environment and living conditions for inhabitants of the Eastern and North-<br />

Eastern parts of the Budapest agglomeration.<br />

[Emphasis added]<br />

Originally, the preparatory phase was to only last until the third quarter of 2001,<br />

with construction running from 2002 to the third quarter of 2006. Feasibility studies for<br />

this section are still underway, however. However, although ISPA was expected as early<br />

as 2002, to date, no EU funding has been approved for this section. In terms of local<br />

resistance, less controversy is expected to ensue over this particular section since the<br />

environmental areas to be crossed are considered less environmentally sensitive, and<br />

local communities to be less affected. This impression, of course, may change as new<br />

NIMBY (Not-In-My-Backyard) groups rise to the fore, new details from the feasibility<br />

studies emerge and new land use development plans in the wake of (or rather,<br />

anticipating) the ring road become public.<br />

9.2.4 The Western Section and the M0 Bridge: New priorities from 2002<br />

Although neither foreseen under TINA nor under the previous Hungarian<br />

government national highway plans, the Budapest municipality, with the support of the<br />

new socialist national government, has recently pushed the idea of constructing a new<br />

bridge over the Danube and continuing the M0 on the Western side. As a July 4, 2002<br />

CEE Bankwatch/CAAG press release reads:<br />

Two environmental NGOs, the Central and Eastern European Bankwatch Network and<br />

the Clean Air Action Group, were astonished to learn of the June 26 statement by<br />

István Csillag, Hungarian Minister of Economics and Transport, and Gábor Demszky,<br />

the Mayor of Budapest, saying that the Municipality can now count on the<br />

government's support in constructing … a bridge over the Danube north of Budapest<br />

and sections of the M0 ring road on the river's western bank. The statement also


370<br />

included information that the Government and the Municipality would apply for<br />

funding from the European Investment Bank (EIB) to fund these projects. 4<br />

The environmental groups were highly alarmed and critical of these plans.<br />

Whether or not they quickly become reality remains to be seen. The accelerated full<br />

completion of the Budapest ring road is indeed the key difference between the long-term<br />

transport plans of the new social-democratic government and the old Orbàn government.<br />

Transport and Economy minister István Csillag and Budapest Mayor Gábor Demsky<br />

optimistically announced the completion of both the new M0 bridge and the ring as a<br />

whole for as early as 2006. Nevertheless, the exact location of the bridge (as other<br />

alignments of the ring road) is still disputed; two options about 4 miles apart from each<br />

other are currently being considered. The Clean Air Action Group has already brought a<br />

court case against one of the two locations. Despite the renewed interest in the<br />

construction, so far, neither the national government nor the EIB have committed any<br />

concrete funds to develop this section, although this might soon be the case.<br />

9.3 Arguments For and Against the M0 Ring Road: A Typology<br />

Table 9.1 gives an overview of the key arguments for and against the M0 ring<br />

road, organizing them into the five discursive frameworks for sustainable transport<br />

decision-making identified earlier in this study. It also lists the key promoters and<br />

opponents of the infrastructure. Key arguments for the ring road are listed under the<br />

ecological modernization ideal. 5<br />

Arguments against the road, or rather: objections raised<br />

against some of the substantive and the procedural sub-aspects of its planning process,<br />

4 Online under http://www.bankwatch.org/press/2002/press98.html, last accessed September 6, 2002.<br />

5 Note that many of these positive effects are also recognized within the other frameworks, even if these<br />

frameworks ultimately do not consider them the most decisive arguments in the decision-making process.


371<br />

are then listed within the four alternative discursive frameworks. The details of the<br />

arguments are discussed in later sections.<br />

In general, arguments unequivocally speaking for the ring road are rather<br />

consistent at the local, national and international levels: the bypass road is to speed up<br />

traffic, avoid congestion in the center, improve accessibility and road safety. In terms of<br />

cost-benefit calculations, travel time savings (for both passenger and freight travel) and<br />

improved road safety were the weightiest arguments for the ring road (as demonstrated in<br />

the ISPA grant request and the EIB funding justifications). 6<br />

Arguments against the construction of the ring road are more varied, and can be<br />

divided into four categories, paralleling the four alternative frameworks. First of all,<br />

there are the impacts the road is likely to have on the surrounding natural habitat, i.e.<br />

local ecosystem balance. Although also recognized within other discursive frameworks,<br />

such “habitat preservation” arguments only take priority under the discursive framework<br />

of renunciation. Giving absolute priority to ecology of course means taking a fully antidevelopment<br />

perspective and opposing the construction of any roads.<br />

Secondly, there are political economy arguments focusing on the road’s effects on<br />

Budapest residents with regard to health and noise impacts, as well as alternative modal<br />

options. Here, the challenge lies in finding a solution that most fairly distributes both the<br />

positive and the negative impacts amongst citizens. Of course, such a locally focused<br />

appraisal is bound to be at odds with an appraisal that “adds the European dimension,”<br />

6 Note that despite this pre-construction rhetoric, I dropped the road safety argument from the above table.<br />

The reason for this is that empirical evidence was to the contrary. The completed southern section of the<br />

M0 did not feature any separation between the lanes and turned out to be an especially unsafe highway,<br />

leading to the unfavorable nickname “Death Road” both in the media and the public at large. Empirical<br />

data presented by the ministry show that accidents with light and serious casualty rose sharply on the M0<br />

after 1993, peaking in 1995. Levels are now going down, however, since the government retrofit the M0<br />

with additional safety features (dividers, reflectors, additional information panels) and increased police<br />

presence to avoid speeding (for detailed data, see Ruppert 2001).


372<br />

i.e. an appraisal that includes the time-saving benefits to all passenger and freight<br />

transport using the infrastructure, and not just local residents. The problem is that longdistance<br />

travelers only reap the benefits of the ring road, but have to bear none of its local<br />

environmental burdens. (This is also mostly true for Budapest’s inner-city residents.)<br />

Thirdly, communicative rationality arguments relate to the assessment and<br />

decision-making process leading up to the construction of the road. In other words: such<br />

arguments do not immediately question the substance of the arguments in favor of the<br />

ring road, but instead focus on the procedural aspects of the planning process, and object,<br />

for example, to deficiencies in the public information, democratic participation and<br />

environmental assessments procedures prior to the ring road construction. This line of<br />

argument is, of course, also consistent with the fourth and last alternative discursive<br />

framework of reflexive modernization, since the concept of “risk rationality” also<br />

strongly relies on the ability of decision-making bodies to fully and adequately capture<br />

all social and environmental costs and benefits of planned transport infrastructures during<br />

the assessment stage, and to then approve or reject (i.e. prevent) a project accordingly.<br />

Finally, there is an important line of argument relating to longer-term regional<br />

impacts of the ring road, notably the impact on the future of the urban economic structure<br />

(“sprawl”) and on modal splits (i.e. a move towards a more car-oriented system). This<br />

line of argument is not easily associated with one single discursive framework. I have<br />

grouped it in the reflexive modernization category, since a truly consistent risk rational<br />

approach which is concerned about unintended consequences and thus cautious to take<br />

preventive action would seem the most likely arena for these issues to gain currency. In<br />

a way, one might also say that the reflexive modernization framework offers a much


373<br />

more progressive variant of the ecological modernization decision-making framework<br />

with a heightened precautionary, future-oriented, more comprehensive consciousness. 7<br />

As below accounts will show, the threat of detrimental medium- to long term<br />

modal and land-use impacts related to the construction of the ring road is real, yet<br />

relatively unaccounted for in current decision-making structures. Anti-sprawl and modal<br />

bias arguments are frequently championed by advocacy-oriented NGOs (see Barnes<br />

2001, especially the quote in section 9.5 below), but to date, neither the local Hungarian<br />

governments nor the EU institutions have firmly addressed the issue. We will come back<br />

to this important point in the conclusion.<br />

Now, in order to put this still somewhat abstract typology on a fully reality-based<br />

footing, the following section will show how all these different viewpoints and arguments<br />

played out in one concrete case. As evident from above overview, each section of the<br />

ring road has been, or is still to be, built under a particular, shifting set of circumstances,<br />

so that convincing rationalities for building or not building one stretch of the highway<br />

will not necessarily apply to all other parts of the M0. I will therefore limit my close-up<br />

view in the next section to the stretch of the M0 whose construction has been the most<br />

controversial so far, namely the section between the old National road No. 2 and the M2<br />

highway in the North.<br />

7 Note that for the sake of completion, it is worth pointing out one additional position, namely the<br />

“alternative investments” argument. Such a position would discourage any new infrastructure investments<br />

in the comparatively wealthy Budapest regions and instead favor investments in less privileged and poorer<br />

settlements in Hungary. This position, which might best be grouped in the political-economy category, is<br />

consistent with certain EU and national arguments for spatial cohesion and greater polycentricity.<br />

However, although politicians from rural Eastern Hungary indeed do object to many additional large-scale<br />

infrastructure funds going into the capital, this did not really carry any weight in the actual debate around<br />

the M0. Also remember that with regard to local-level political economy arguments, depending on the<br />

local actor’s personal viewpoint and economic situation, the same impact (e.g. mushrooming of<br />

hypermarkets) can be of course perceived as positive (e.g. cheaper, one-stop shopping, potential for local<br />

employment) or negative (destroyed nature recreation area, threatens small local shopkeepers).


374<br />

Table 9.1 Main Arguments for & Objections against the M0 Ring Road Plans<br />

Mainstream<br />

Policy Goals<br />

Arguments in favor of<br />

the M0 Plans<br />

Key Proponents<br />

Ecological<br />

Modernization<br />

“Sustainable<br />

Growth”<br />

Network Expansion<br />

High-Speed<br />

transport<br />

Managed Growth<br />

“Missing Link”:<br />

Key international &<br />

national transit node<br />

“Bottleneck”:<br />

Effective bypass,<br />

helps Budapest growth<br />

EU,<br />

IFIs,<br />

Hungarian national<br />

government,<br />

Budapest<br />

municipality<br />

Alternative<br />

Concerns<br />

Objections raised<br />

against the M0 Plans<br />

Key Opponents 8<br />

Reflexive<br />

Modernization<br />

“Risk<br />

rationality”<br />

Precautionary<br />

Principle?<br />

Unintended<br />

Consequences?<br />

Longer term land use<br />

impacts (sprawl)<br />

Increased motorization<br />

International<br />

sustainable transport<br />

advocacy groups:<br />

ITDP, T&E<br />

Communicative<br />

Rationality<br />

“Rationality”<br />

Participation?<br />

Access to<br />

Information?<br />

Democracy?<br />

Faulty participation<br />

procedures, no adequate<br />

public information<br />

Faulty EIA (wrong maps,<br />

no dispersion model used<br />

for pollution impacts, etc)<br />

EU Environmental<br />

NGOs:<br />

FOEE, European<br />

Environment Bureau<br />

CEE-wide NGOs:<br />

CEE Bankwatch<br />

Political<br />

Economy<br />

Equity & Social<br />

Justice<br />

Renunciation<br />

“Ecological<br />

Balance”<br />

Who benefits?<br />

Impacts on<br />

citizens?<br />

Land use<br />

consumption?<br />

Effect on overall<br />

mobility?<br />

Impact on habitats?<br />

Privileges car owners<br />

Lack of parallel<br />

investments into transit<br />

Health & noise impacts<br />

on local residents<br />

New greenfield land take<br />

Severance effects<br />

Inadequate measures for<br />

protected bush<br />

Sensitive ecosystems in<br />

the Buda Hills<br />

Local municipalities<br />

in Dunakeszi<br />

Local citizens:<br />

Káposztásmegyer<br />

Environmental<br />

Protection Society<br />

Local environmental<br />

NGOs:<br />

Clean Air Action<br />

Group<br />

8 ITDP is the Institute for Transportation and Development Policy, based in New York City. This<br />

international transport advocacy NGO has worked closely with the Hungarian Clean Air Action Group on<br />

many CEE transport issues over the last decade and provided key support on the M0 case. T&E is the<br />

acronym for the European Federation for Transport and Environment, the umbrella organization of<br />

European Traffic Clubs. FOEE is Friends of the Earth Europe, an umbrella organization of environmental<br />

NGOs based in Brussels. CEE Bankwatch monitors IFI activity in the CEE region, with a particular focus<br />

on the EIB. The Clean Air Action Group is a Hungarian national federation of over 80 individual NGOs.


375<br />

9.4 Local and International Protests Against the Northern Section of the M0 9<br />

The Northern extension of the MO ring road was a heavily contested construction<br />

project which set two environmental precedents. For one, it was the first case in postsocialist<br />

Hungary, and in fact in post-socialist Central Europe at large, where local civic<br />

and environmental groups managed to get a local court to issue an injunction to halt the<br />

completion of a large-scale transport infrastructure on the basis of faulty environmental<br />

assessments. Secondly and equally extraordinary, a large part of the fight against the<br />

road was not only carried out in Budapest, but also in Brussels and Luxemburg, the seats<br />

of the European Union Commission and the European Investment Bank, respectively.<br />

For the first time, international environmental groups managed to bring a case before the<br />

EU Ombudsman that prompted an investigation into the lending assessment practices of<br />

the European Investment Bank. The circumstances of the case are therefore instructive<br />

for European Union decision-making in the transport sector, and for transport decisionmaking<br />

with regard to the enlargement countries in particular.<br />

While the Hungarian government and the European Investment Bank take a<br />

predictable pro-investment ecological modernization position in this dispute,<br />

environmental and civic organizations, together with local communities, brought forth a<br />

variety of communicative rationality, political economy and renunciation arguments to<br />

fight this development.<br />

9 Much of the key correspondence of the case is contained in a special “M0 Dossier” prepared by the CEE<br />

Bankwatch Network in January 2000. I included additional information and updates from my own<br />

interviews, site visits and email correspondence with the relevant stakeholders. Additional information on<br />

the (NGOs’ interpretation of the) M0 case can also be found in Feiler and Stoczkiewicz (1999). For the<br />

very first time, the EIB has recently begun to more pro-actively respond to the repeated NGO attacks<br />

regarding this case by presenting some of their own views on their web page.


376<br />

Contrary to the Southern section, there was opposition against the planned<br />

Northern section of the M0 from the very start. The environmental impacts of the project<br />

were expected to be much worse than those for the Southern section. It was also deemed<br />

a less-necessary undertaking, so that the environmentalists also argued that this money<br />

should be better spent on upgrading existing infrastructures, especially since Hungary<br />

was and is still facing a very severe backlog in road maintenance even on key<br />

international motorways. Along with environmental groups, two district municipalities in<br />

Budapest and four nearby towns opposed the construction of the M0 on their territory.<br />

Nevertheless, against strong local protests and as the environmentalists point out, “in<br />

violation of several Hungarian laws,” the first part of the northern section between the<br />

M3 motorway and the old road Nr. 2 was eventually completed, using part of the € 72<br />

million loan from the EIB as well as part of the € 14.26 million from Phare.<br />

The arguments of environmental and civic groups opposed to the construction of<br />

the Northern section of the M0 were multiple. Yet not all of them carried equal weight in<br />

the actual court cases. Interestingly, there was next to no way of effectively including<br />

“sprawl” related arguments into the environmental and civic fight against it, since the<br />

required standardized EU environmental assessment methodologies and cost benefit<br />

analyses (which, given its candidate status, should now also be binding for Hungary) do<br />

not require consideration of longer-term spatial effects. Consequently, the actual legal<br />

case against the Northern section of the M0 reads much more like a classical NIMBY and<br />

ecological activist case than it might have otherwise been. Not withstanding this nonapplicability<br />

of additional sprawl arguments, the case brought forward by the<br />

environmentalists shows how controversial the investment was.


377<br />

The permission plan and the EIA of the project show that the route was going to<br />

pass through an area protected under the Hungarian Act 53/1996 on Nature Protection<br />

inhabited by a protected bush. The route was also situated about 300 meters away from a<br />

housing estate called Káposztásmegyer II that houses about 5000 people. A junction was<br />

planned only 150 meters away from the local nursery, with the public access roads<br />

leading up to it less than 15 meters away from residences and key social institutions<br />

including a kindergarten and primary school. According to assessments presented by the<br />

Clean Air Action Group, the network of civic and environmental organizations that led<br />

the protest against the case, permissible air pollution levels in the area were to be<br />

exceeded by up to 30% and noise levels would reach up to 76 dB during the day and up<br />

to 68 dB at night, thus also greatly exceeding permissible levels (of 65 and 55 dB,<br />

respectively) according to WHO and EU standards (also see picture 9.1).<br />

Picture 9.1: Construction of the Northern Section of the M0 ring road with the<br />

Káposztásmegzer II Housing Estate in the background.<br />

Photo Credit: Feiler and Stoczkiewicz (1999:22)


378<br />

The environmental groups further pointed to faulty public participation<br />

procedures to explain the fact that nobody from the community participated in the public<br />

hearing at which the plans were discussed for the first time. Contrary to official<br />

requirements, the hearing was not announced in any major newspaper, and only sixteen<br />

official representatives attended the meeting. Hence, almost all residents first learned of<br />

the projects when the actual construction began in the spring of 1998. When the<br />

concerned citizens of Káposztásmegyer II immediately formed a protest organization, the<br />

Káposztásmegyer Environmental Protection Society, and began their investigations, they<br />

found out that their own housing estate had not been on the map used by the motorway<br />

company when it applied for the construction permit. Only Káposztásmegyer I, which<br />

was more than a mile further away from the future site of the M0, was drawn on the map.<br />

After two unsuccessful trials which were appealed, the Capital Court of Budapest<br />

sided with the environmentalists and issued an injunction to halt construction in the<br />

northern section of the M0. Nevertheless, the citizens and the NGOs eventually lost the<br />

case and the road was opened to traffic anyway at the end of October 1999, with only one<br />

modification: the last 50 meters leading up from junction 2 remained unbuilt, so that the<br />

M0 cannot be reached directly from the residential area.<br />

Despite this defeat, both the NGO fight inside Hungary and the European fight<br />

against the EIB’s involvement in the case dragged on much beyond this date. They<br />

turned to the EU Ombudsman who is entitled to investigate possible incidents of<br />

maladministration in the EU.<br />

Projects funded with inadequate environmental<br />

assessments would fall under this category. Interestingly, it was not possible for the<br />

Hungarian environmental groups to directly bring their complaint to the Ombudsman,


379<br />

since only citizens or legal persons of the EU are authorized to voice such complaints,<br />

regardless of the fact that in this case EU funding outside its current borders was at issue.<br />

The complaint therefore had to be officially handed in by the head of the European<br />

Environmental Bureau (EEB), a large, Brussels-based environmental umbrella<br />

organization.<br />

When the Ombudsman’s office was not content with the materials provided by the<br />

EIB president in response to the investigation requested by the environmentalists, the<br />

Ombudsman requested additional information, which the EIB initially refused to provide,<br />

citing Article 237(c) of the Community Treaty according to which decision’s of the EIB’s<br />

Board of Directors are not subject to judicial review. The Ombudsman pointed out that<br />

the activities of the Ombudsman are instead governed by Article 195 of the Treaty and<br />

that “the Ombudsman conducts inquiries … concerning instances of maladministration in<br />

the activities of the Community institutions or bodies… Specifically, it does not provide<br />

for any exception relating to the EIB. 10<br />

The EIB eventually complied and supplied<br />

additional information.<br />

In the end, the environmentalists’ fight against the M0 and the EIB illustrates two<br />

fundamentally different interpretations of what EU-led sustainable transport development<br />

in CEE means. Three excepts from the respective correspondence serve well to illustrate<br />

this opposition. The environmentalists argued that:<br />

The M0 orbital motorway is called an ‘environmental project’ because it is said to<br />

have positive impacts on Budapest’s transit traffic. The northern sector of this road,<br />

however, is actually an unnecessary part of the project, having more disadvantages<br />

than advantages for the quality of life, not only for the local citizens affected, but also<br />

for a much wider area. 11<br />

10 Letter by the European Union Ombudsman to Sir Brian Unwin, President of the EIB. Cited in Feiler and<br />

Stoczkiewicz (1999:23).<br />

11 Background Information Sheet, in: CEE Bankwatch Network (2000)


380<br />

In its initial reply, the EIB only provided a short two-paragraph response to the<br />

Ombudsman request to supply additional information, noting that:<br />

The EIB only supports projects in the Central European countries which fulfill the<br />

European Union’s broader aim to assist the adoption of the EU body of laws and<br />

standards in order to prepare these countries for membership in the European Union.<br />

With regard to the transport sector, the EU council of Ministers has confirmed the<br />

importance of strategic highways linking EU Member States with accession<br />

countries as part of the preparation of EU membership. … It is not for the bank to<br />

comment on national legal procedures for granting project permits and other<br />

permissions.<br />

So we find a justification very much based on Pan-European efficiency and the<br />

requirement for national modernization of infrastructure. Then, after repeated and more<br />

forceful requests by the Ombudsman demanding EIB cooperation, the EIB, with a long<br />

letter dated December 14, 1999 that contained several annexes, supplied specific<br />

information on the M0 case. Here, a paragraph entitled “Objective of the by-pass<br />

construction” is particularly revealing:<br />

The objective of the by-pass construction is to reduce existing severe<br />

environmental degradation (noise, vibration, air pollution and road traffic<br />

hazards) caused by traffic crossing central Budapest as well as the agglomeration<br />

of Dunakeszi, Göd, Szödliget and Vac, north of the capital, where the residential<br />

population runs into the tens of thousands. The fact that by-pass projects which are –<br />

like the present one – designed to reduce serious environmental degradation in major<br />

urban areas run close to or even impinge on certain other existing buildings is not<br />

uncommon, and is often unavoidable if the overall improvement which is the aim and<br />

purpose of such schemes is to be achieved. The analysis of these aspects, positive and<br />

negative, are among the subjects of Environmental Impact Studies. 12<br />

This statement is interesting in that rationales and rhetoric are completely<br />

different from the first response letter. The EIB now claims the need for the M0 as an<br />

12 Annex of a letter written to Mr. Jacob Södermann, the European Ombudsman, by Sri Brian Unwin, the<br />

President of the EIB, on December 13, 1999. Copy supplied in: CEE Bankwatch Network (2000)


381<br />

environmental matter. Moreover, the EIB immediately relegates the level of debate to<br />

the realm of possible specific procedural shortcomings, only admitting that “the<br />

complaint reflects a disagreement on the judgments that have been made in the<br />

assessment of certain environmental aspects, and on the way in which these have been<br />

weighed against other aspects of the project,” as the body of the letter itself explains it.<br />

At question, then, are no longer the rationales for the investment itself, which have now<br />

been reincarnated as objective environmental needs, but only the technical expertise with<br />

which it was administered. Even the blame for eventual procedural flaws is put on the<br />

Hungarian government as the project promoter. Environmental and citizen advocacy<br />

groups thus rightfully point to a continued discrepancy between an EU-advocated<br />

rhetoric of highly integrated, transparent, all-inclusive, “reflexive” decision-making on<br />

one hand, and a continued reality of a firmly un-self-critical EIB on the other hand, i.e. an<br />

EU house bank which provides infrastructure financing under comparatively nontransparent,<br />

inconsistent decision-making rationales.<br />

9.5 Risk-rational Concerns: Is Brussels Co-financing Urban Sprawl in Budapest?<br />

Beyond the more locally substantive and procedurally focused legal action against<br />

the EIB, international environmental groups have since increasingly begun to question<br />

EU funding for ring roads in general, and those in connection with TEN network<br />

completion in particular. The current NGO viewpoint in this regard was best summarized<br />

by Jim Barnes of Friends of the Earth Europe (2001:6) in a speech at the Trans-European<br />

Transport Networks Conference organized by the EIB in Strasbourg. The argument is<br />

multi-dimensional and worth quoting at length:


382<br />

Many of the links that are being built in the CEE with EU funds are in fact ring roads<br />

or bypass roads. While for small cities these roads play a positive role of diverting<br />

truck traffic out of city centers, in primary cities these ring roads are serving over 90%<br />

local traffic, and over 90% of the destination of the traffic is the major city. The<br />

construction of these ring roads with EU money, most notably in Budapest and Sofia<br />

but others as well, is by far the strongest inducement to suburban sprawl. These ring<br />

roads have set off a spree of real estate speculation, big box retail mall development,<br />

and increasingly of suburban housing that is fundamentally transforming urban traffic<br />

patterns from a downtown public transit focus to an ex-urban automobile dependence.<br />

These urban changes are dramatically increasing Vehicle Kilometers Traveled in CEE<br />

cities, driving most into violation of the EU’s directive on NOx. While these ring<br />

roads dramatically reduce the cost of car trips in suburban areas, as they are heavily<br />

subsidized with EU grants and concessional loans, they are creating unfair competition<br />

with existing public transit systems that are not, for all practical purposes, eligible for<br />

any EU funds. Because these ring roads serve primarily local traffic, and compete<br />

directly with public transit systems, they should either be disallowed as eligible for EU<br />

funding as not being key to ‘integration’, or they should be supported only in a context<br />

where EU funding supporting urban surface public transit systems is also found.<br />

This is quite a complex and sophisticated argument. Moreover, it is an argument<br />

that does not necessarily preclude the construction of the ring road as such, but rather<br />

criticizes politicians and funders for not sufficiently taking all possible medium- to longterm<br />

effects of this road into account in their decision-making process. In other words, it<br />

is - at its minimum - a reflexive modernization-type argument which calls for<br />

precautionary mitigating measures that might counteract the unwanted and unintended<br />

consequences of this large-scale infrastructure. Alternatively, the environmentalists of<br />

course also mean to imply that should the apparently currently ignored modal and land<br />

use effects of the M0 turn out to be as massively detrimental as they fear, this would be<br />

grounds not to construct any additional sections of the ring road. This is where the<br />

argument touches upon issues of intra-regional and intergenerational equity, and<br />

therefore turns into a more full-blown political economy argument.


383<br />

9.5.5 Reexamining the impact of ring roads on travel & land use<br />

In order to be able to better evaluate the important objections to the M0 regarding<br />

its future environmental risks of sprawl and increased car use, I will now take a brief look<br />

at the state-of-the-art knowledge on the impact of ring roads on travel and land use<br />

patterns. As already noted above, in theory, ring roads are designed to divert traffic away<br />

from city centers in order to avoid congestion in the core. They are seen as being<br />

beneficial both to the inner city populations who will no longer be affected by the<br />

negative impacts of transit traffic passing through their neighborhoods, and to the road<br />

users for whom the by-pass affords substantial time savings. Unfortunately, this<br />

otherwise impeccable logic has two central flaws: first, it ignores the medium to longterm<br />

effects that high-speed, limited-access ring roads have on overall land-use and travel<br />

patterns in the region, and second, it intentionally re-locates local environmental impacts,<br />

namely noise, air pollution and severance effects, from one location to another, thereby<br />

pre-programming LULU 13<br />

/ NIMBY reactions. It is the first, much more complex<br />

problem which concerns us in this section.<br />

The strongest general counter-argument against expanding high-speed road<br />

capacities whenever congestion occurs is that a temporary easing of traffic conditions<br />

will in fact induce additional travel, thus causing additional congestion in the medium to<br />

long term. The issue remains a matter of academic dispute, although evidence in support<br />

of this interpretation has been mounting in recent decades. At least for the case of peakhour<br />

travel on limited access roads, Anthony Downs (1962; 1992) has by now rather<br />

thoroughly debunked the myth that it is possible to build one’s way out of congestion.<br />

13 Land uses perceived as detrimental to a particular area by nearby residents are often called LULUs (=<br />

locally unwanted land uses) . What is considered a LULU varies throughout a city and also depends upon<br />

the affluence and history of the neighborhood.


384<br />

Hence, the main economic argument in favor of ring roads, namely user time savings,<br />

tends to disappear over time.<br />

As for the medium- to long-term impacts of ring roads on travel patterns,<br />

metropolitan structures, and – by extension – on the future competitiveness of the<br />

agglomeration at hand, there is also no consensus in the literature. Crane (1999) provides<br />

an excellent, exhaustive, albeit predominantly U.S.-centered overview of the rapidly<br />

growing literature investigating causal links between urban form and travel, concluding<br />

that “while research … is improving in several respects, our current understanding of<br />

these relationships remains poor.” Crane’s main aim, however, was to assess the scope<br />

for using land use as a determinant of affecting travel behavior, rather than the other way<br />

around.<br />

Four recent European studies explicitly investigate the effects of ring roads on<br />

metropolitan development: Guitérrez and Gómez (1999) in Spain, Linneker and Spence<br />

(1996) in Britain, and van Nes (2002) in Britain, Germany and Norway, and Falleth<br />

(1999) in Norway. 14 Guitérrez and Gómez focus on measuring intra-metropolitan<br />

accessibility, but most of their conclusions are rather tentative. Interestingly, the<br />

investigated M40 ring road in Madrid was completed as recently as 1990-96 to relieve<br />

congestion on an older, inner orbital motorway, the M30. The main rationale for the M40<br />

was thus never to serve as a transit bypass, but always to accommodate increasing traffic<br />

between the city center and suburban municipalities. In the end, Guitiérrez and Gómez<br />

(1999:14) conclude that<br />

14 In fact, Falleth’s study does not investigate ring roads but by-passes, i.e. partial ring-roads that are not<br />

designed to encircle the entire town or city. The study remains highly relevant to our case study, however,<br />

since this is of course what the M0 is in its current form.


385<br />

Orbital motorways do not necessarily lead to an increase in equality in the distribution<br />

of intra-metropolitan accessibility, for this will depend on their location within the<br />

metropolitan area: … the further in they are, the more traffic they will attract and the<br />

less extensive will be the area over which greater equality is brought about in the<br />

decentralization of accessibility.<br />

These conclusions thus seem to confirm the worry expressed by the NGOs that<br />

urban ring roads bring about problematic shifts in travel patterns. The second example,<br />

Linneker’s and Spence’s study on the regional development effects of the M25 London<br />

orbital motorway, is of limited transferability since their computer model heavily relied<br />

on regional employment data whose dynamics are rather particular to the British case. In<br />

addition, their results ran counter to previous research in the area, and their ultimate,<br />

“safe bet” conclusion was restricted to the insight that “accessibility improvements are<br />

not mono-causal and unilateral in their impact” (p.90). Taking a rather different<br />

approach, Van Nes’ (2002) Ph.D. thesis used the so-called space-syntax approach<br />

developed Bill Hillier and his colleagues at University College London – a method<br />

normally mostly used to predict “the likely effects of architectural and urban design<br />

choices” (Hillier 1999:345) - to present eight different European case studies on ring<br />

roads and urban change. Her research uses historical data on shops and puts it in relation<br />

to changes in the configuration and integration of the overall street grid. Although they<br />

do not take into account the influence of land use and transport policies on shop<br />

relocation, her space syntax models are able to explain significant differences in the way<br />

the ring roads affected the various town centers. One of her main conclusions is that<br />

“apparently, it is not the ring road that attracts the establishment of new retailers and<br />

shops, but the way in which the ring road is connected to the urban grid on which it was<br />

imposed” (van Nes 2002:18). Finally, Falleth’s study specifically investigated suburban


386<br />

growth and land actors along by-pass roads in Norway. The results of her research are<br />

the most relevant to the Budapest case, since the main point of contention in Budapest is<br />

also suburban sprawl. Falleth summarizes her findings as follows (Falleth 1999:357):<br />

It has been argued that by-pass roads lead to suburban growth and that the construction<br />

of such roads will prompt the planning of industrial and other commercial<br />

developments, on the part of the local municipal government. This case study of five<br />

by-pass roads shows that a significant, but limited suburban growth takes place along<br />

these roads.<br />

So although the investigated towns were neither undergoing rapid transition nor<br />

were they of a size comparable to Budapest, the respective by-passes still induced<br />

“significant” suburban growth. This conclusion is consistent with the results from the<br />

recent OECD study “Managing Urban Growth” (2000b), which also found that one of the<br />

major factors facilitating sprawl is the development of high-speed access roads around<br />

urban centers. Also note that in the case of Norway, this growth occurred despite the<br />

existence of explicit national policies targeted to curb urban sprawl. 15<br />

As Falleth explains<br />

(p. 358):<br />

An increasing number of political restrictions have been laid down through national<br />

guidelines on suburban growth along by-pass roads. … These guidelines are more<br />

restrictive to the construction of new exit roads from the by-pass roads and to<br />

suburban growth along the roads. The Ministry of Environment has singled out<br />

densification within the urban area as a national policy for urban growth since the<br />

1980s to avoid further urban sprawl.<br />

Many European countries now have similar policies, confirming that anti-sprawl<br />

sentiments are the new mainstream of EU urban policy (for an excellent up-to-date<br />

overview of policies, see Baar 2002).<br />

15 Falleth’s study also points to the key role local and regional governments have in either supporting or<br />

discouraging private investment adjacent to the infrastructures. As we will see, this is a key issue in the<br />

case of Budapest as well.


387<br />

At this point, a suitable definition of the term urban sprawl seems in order.<br />

“Sprawl” is generally used to describe unfavorable expansions of urban settlements into<br />

the surrounding landscape, and it carries extremely negative connotations because of the<br />

very inefficient, resource-intensive land use and transport patterns associated with it. In<br />

an attempt to provide a common definition of the term, the OECD (2000b) concluded that<br />

sprawl could be recognized though 1) relative low density, 2) a pattern of land<br />

consumption which is characterized by outward growth with particular patterns such as<br />

leapfrog development and small area development alongside trunk roads, and 3) the<br />

absence of strategic planning, with little capacity to cope with unplanned land use and<br />

monofunctionality. As discussed below, all three factors are relevant in the Budapest<br />

case. In another, frequently cited study, Duany, Plater-Zyberg and Speck (2000:5) also<br />

stress the issue of monofunctionality, finding that “the dominant characteristic of sprawl<br />

is that each component [of sprawl] is strictly segregated from the others.” They identify<br />

five components of sprawl: roadways, housing subdivisions, shopping centers (also<br />

variously named shopping malls or big box retail), office/business parks, and civic<br />

institutions. With the exception of the latter, all five of those uses are presently<br />

mushrooming around Budapest. And although a ring road in and of itself does not cause<br />

a segregation of uses, the on and exit ramps of urban highways have always been<br />

preferred locations for leapfrog development.<br />

9.5.6 The role of the M0 in spurring ex-urban development in Budapest<br />

Returning to our Budapest case study, it is certain that the key role the M0 is<br />

playing in spurring ex-urban development is not an invention of environmentalists. New


388<br />

greenfield developments are springing up around the M0 and its adjacent areas at a rapid<br />

pace and on a massive scale. Most local and national decision-makers hail these<br />

developments as positive signs of economic growth in the Budapest region, and both the<br />

municipal and the national governments are strongly supportive of the various industrial<br />

parks and warehousing facilities spring up alongside the new road infrastructures.<br />

Yet greenfield investments are problematic both from the point of view of the city<br />

of Budapest and from a larger sustainability perspective. Most development occurs just<br />

outside the city limits, where accessibility is high but land prices are still cheap, so the<br />

city incurs significant revenue losses from residential and commercial uses. Instead of<br />

re-using the extensive brownfield sites in Budapest’s de-industrialized transition zones<br />

located in relative proximity to the historical core, large multinationals are instead<br />

attracted to greenfield sites offered to them by suburban communities and/or developers<br />

at low market prices (also see Colliers International 2001:44). Almost all of these<br />

greenfield developments are of the big box retail kind that is considered a classic example<br />

of auto-oriented urban sprawl.<br />

Developments near the southern end of the M0 near the intersection with the<br />

M1/M7 are particularly striking, with an increasing number of big box retail functions<br />

locating there (see examples in picture 9.2). Moreover, residential sprawl in the<br />

environmentally sensitive hills around Budaörs and elsewhere near the M0 is becoming a<br />

major problem (see picture 9.3). (Note that the excellent accessibility of Budaörs with<br />

regard to other parts of the agglomeration is of course not only due to its proximity to the<br />

southern part of the M0 ring road, but also due to its location adjacent to the M1/M7<br />

highways which lead straight into the center of Budapest.)


389<br />

Besides retail and industrial parks, the southern section of the M0 has also<br />

attracted scores of new logistical and warehousing facilities (see figures 9.3 and 9.4). Far<br />

exceeding the space requirements even of big box retail, these new uses take advantage<br />

of the strategic location of Budapest in Central Europe. Although problematic from a<br />

conservationist perspective, these greenfield developments are more difficult to assess in<br />

terms of overall transport sustainability, since several of them consist of traffic-intensive,<br />

distributive functions that are rightfully being relocated from Budapest’s more central<br />

districts to the ring road. On the other hand, many of the new businesses relocated from<br />

Vienna (the current logistics hub in Central Europe) and elsewhere, thus bringing new<br />

traffic into the region rather than relocating existing traffic from the Budapest center. A<br />

key question in terms of longer-term sustainable transport development is whether the<br />

logistic centers will be predominantly truck based, or whether they will also rely on rail<br />

and combined transport. As figure 9.4 shows, so far the biggest centers developed where<br />

the M0 intersects with both other highways and rail lines.<br />

In the North, investments are also taking off now that the M0 link near the M3<br />

and M2 highways is completed. The most problematic is a giant shopping center. In<br />

October 2001, shortly after environmental challenges against the development plans had<br />

been defeated in court, the French multinational Auchan opened their largest hypermarket<br />

in the world (19,600 m 2 ) immediately next to the disputed, EIB and Phare-co-funded M0<br />

junction by Dunakeszi. The environmentalists had fought the development on the<br />

grounds that the development was planned on a wetland that should be preserved. Since<br />

the M0 is located at the edges of the municipal boundaries of the City of Budapest, the<br />

city has little influence on these developments, and the local communities surrounding


390<br />

Budapest are eagerly competing for investment, frequently offering land to developers<br />

that was not originally intended for development.<br />

Picture 9.2<br />

Big Box Retail along the M1/7 & M0 Highways in Budaörs: IKEA and Auchan<br />

Auchan<br />

Hypermarket<br />

IKEA<br />

Photo Credit: Deike Peters (2000)<br />

(View from the Budaörs Hills)<br />

Picture 9.3<br />

New single-family homes in the environmentally sensitive hills of Budaörs<br />

Photo credit: Deike Peters (2000)


391<br />

Figure 9.2 New construction of warehouse/logistic facilities along the M0, M1 & M7<br />

Supply<br />

(in m 2 )<br />

120000<br />

80000<br />

40000<br />

0<br />

1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

(expected)<br />

Source: Own compilation, using data from Colliers (2001) and Schneider (2002)<br />

Figure 9.3 Location of the seven largest warehousing centers in the Budapest area<br />

Source: Adapted from HVB Expertise (2001) 16 1 Rosalia Park<br />

Size: 12000m 2 ,Completion: 2000<br />

2 M1 Business Park<br />

Size: 72000m 2 , Completion: 2001<br />

3 Harbor Park<br />

Size: 127000m 2 , Completion: 2001<br />

4 West Gate Business Park<br />

Size: 26000m, Completion: 2001/2<br />

5 Airport Business Park<br />

Size: 50000, Completion 2001<br />

6 Business & Trading<br />

Park Budapest<br />

Size: 400000 (max.), In planning<br />

7 Budapest Intermodal<br />

Logistic Center<br />

Size: 97 ha land, In planning


392<br />

Figures 9.4-5<br />

Auchan Hypermarket next to the EIB- and Phare-funded Section of the M0<br />

Source: Auchan’s Hungarian Website (www.auchan.hu)<br />

9.5.7 The lack of integrated transport and land use decision-making<br />

While a complete review of urban and regional development trends and their<br />

pertaining planning strategies is beyond the scope of this chapter, a few issues with<br />

relevance to the developments alongside the M0 deserve a brief mention. First of all, it<br />

would of course be naïve to believe that the new developments alongside the M0 took<br />

planners and policy-makers in Budapest by surprise. Quite to the contrary, most of them<br />

were locally brokered deals. In the absence of any binding restrictions on greenfield<br />

sites, local communities in close proximity to the ring road continue to compete amongst<br />

each other for new development.<br />

Also, the trend of residential suburbanization from the city center into the<br />

surrounding communities did not begin with the M0 but developed quickly after the<br />

transition (and even before). About 30,000 people move out of the city each year, and<br />

although natural population growth is negative in the entire region, the belt around the


393<br />

city still shows a strong upward trend in population (Ongjerth 1999:7, also see figure<br />

9.7).<br />

Figure 9.6 Residential Suburbanization in the Budapest Agglomeration (1900-2005)<br />

Population changes in the Budapest Agglomeration<br />

(100,000 Persons)<br />

30<br />

25<br />

20<br />

15<br />

10<br />

Budapest<br />

Agglomeration Belt<br />

5<br />

0<br />

1990 1995 2000* 2005*<br />

* Expected<br />

Source: Own compilation using data in Ongjerth (1999)<br />

This trend is particularly worrisome in light of the fact that Budapest not only still<br />

has a functioning high-density core, but also a large number of relatively low-density<br />

districts immediately adjacent to the core (see figure 9.8). This so-called “transition<br />

zone” largely consists of former industrial brownfield sites that became derelict during<br />

post-communist economic restructuring. A truly environmentally “sustainable” transport<br />

and land use strategy for Budapest oriented along EU compact city ideals would have to<br />

concentrate on making this area attractive to investors for mixed-use urban<br />

redevelopment, combining residential, commercial and light industry uses. In particular,<br />

disputed ownership and fuzzy tenure issues would have to be resolved and transit access<br />

improved. At the same time, there would have to be a regional consensus on limiting<br />

greenfield investments in the periphery.


394<br />

Instead, however, the current Budapest Urban Development Strategy is trying to<br />

do a little bit for everyone, somewhat too comfortably promoting redevelopment in the<br />

inner city areas and the transition zone parallel to an active expansion of the southern<br />

M0-M1-M7 highway zone as a key logistical zone as well as a new focus on the so-called<br />

Northern twin cities around the northern end of the M0 (see figure 9.9). The southeastern<br />

area around and beyond the city limits, where residential sprawl also has become<br />

a major factor recently, remained unidentified (at least in Phase II drafts until 1999).<br />

Figure 9.7 The Density Pattern of the City of Budapest<br />

Source: Bertaud (1999)


395<br />

Figure 9.8<br />

Budapest’s “Strategic Zones” according to its Urban Development Strategy<br />

Sources: Pallai, Tosics et al. (1999), Pallai (2000)<br />

Of course, it is always difficult to counteract individual household preferences for<br />

low-density single family suburban homes over multi-family inner-city dwellings,<br />

especially since these preferences were artificially constrained during communist times.<br />

It is equally difficult to keep multinational investors from locating on new greenfield sites<br />

where land is cheaper, accessibility guaranteed and no disputed ownership issues loom.<br />

What additionally exacerbates the problem in the Budapest agglomeration, however, is<br />

the great lack of regional cooperation between inner-city and suburban municipalities.<br />

The city remains in a constant clinch with surrounding communities and competes with<br />

them for foreign and national investment. In fact, the 23 Budapest districts even compete<br />

fiercely amongst each other. Ideas for new administrative bodies in the agglomeration<br />

have been proposed, but no actual decision-making powers have been transferred to the<br />

regional level so far (also see Ongjerth 1999). Too many stakeholders seem to


396<br />

economically benefit from new greenfield developments along the new highways, and<br />

established local actors are not prepared to give up their decision-making powers.<br />

9.5.8 The EU as a partial accomplice in a problematic transformation<br />

In sum, to date, no proper integration of transport and land-use policy-making in<br />

Hungary exists, and no effective regional body is available to strategically direct land-use<br />

developments in the Budapest agglomeration. This problem is not at all particular to<br />

Budapest, of course, but rather a situation that most cities in the world are facing.<br />

However, the key difference in Budapest is that a key EU-funded Pan-European transport<br />

node is at the same time the most decisive factor in spurring ex-urban development.<br />

Considering the high standards which the EU sets for itself in terms of sustainable<br />

transport and land-use development in its policy documents (detailed in Chapter 5), one<br />

might have expected these regional dimensions to play a larger role in the decisionmaking<br />

process. Given its status as a key TEN-extension node, it is highly unlikely that<br />

the EU would have ever come out in disfavor of completing at least the southern, eastern<br />

and northern sections of the M0. However, both the EU and the IFIs might have used<br />

their financial leverage in order to ensure that the construction of the ring road was better<br />

complemented with a regional development strategy that minimized greenfield<br />

development and additional motor vehicle travel. Yet so far, the fragmented, inefficient<br />

regional governance structure has not been a factor in the decision-making process for<br />

any of the EU-related transport funds to Hungary, nor have specific efforts been made to<br />

address suburban-urban conflicts of interest and occurrences of urban sprawl. In light of<br />

the EU’s sizeable and specific financial contributions for road transport infrastructure


397<br />

upgrades in and around the Hungarian capital, there is thus some justification for making<br />

the provocative argument that the EU is at least partly an accomplice in the problematic<br />

transformation that the urban structure of Budapest is currently undergoing.<br />

9.6 Conclusions<br />

This chapter also demonstrated worrying discrepancies between the general<br />

rhetoric of sustainable development and sustainable transport in key EU policy<br />

documents and the actual reality of EU funded transport-sector infrastructure investments<br />

as it affects local environments. Additionally, the case of the Northern section of the M0<br />

demonstrated important deficiencies not only in the argumentative aspects of EU-led<br />

transport investments but also in terms of environmental and social assessment, policy<br />

integration, transparency and public participation and information. Yet persistent<br />

disagreements regarding the details of the planning process leading up to the construction<br />

of the M0 notwithstanding, local citizens’ and ecological concerns could, at least in<br />

theory, be relatively comprehensively addressed within currently existing decisionmaking<br />

procedures. A more stringent, pro-active application of existing public<br />

participation rules and of environmental assessment procedures would certainly have<br />

prevented much angry reactions from local residents. Meanwhile, concerns over longerterm<br />

land use and travel impacts currently have no legalized decision-making framework<br />

in which they could be voiced, neither does the EU seem particularly keen on imposing<br />

such a framework on national or local governments.<br />

Admittedly, given the multiple and conflicting interests connected to the M0, it is<br />

difficult to give a straightforward assessment of whether the costs of the ring road will


398<br />

outweigh the benefits. Besides the disputes over whether the costs and benefits were<br />

calculated correctly, there is also the question of whether their distribution among local<br />

and international actors was fairly assessed and this assessment adequately taken into<br />

account by the international financers of the project. The M0 is therefore an instructive<br />

case study on many levels. It was presented here with a primary view to European Union<br />

institutions as supporters and financers of large-scale infrastructure fulfilling strategic<br />

interests. However, even beyond the challenges of multi-level policy-making, the<br />

dilemma of the construction of the M0 illustrated a number of daunting planning and<br />

policy issues.<br />

The previous section demonstrated that the growth- and mobility-oriented<br />

decision-making rationales which currently dominate EU and Hungarian national and<br />

local-level politics tend to disregard the detrimental long-term regional impacts of largescale<br />

transport infrastructures such as ring roads. Moreoever, the M0 case has also<br />

shown that a variety of alternative aspects such as public accountability, participatory<br />

democracy, mediation of locational conflict, and environmental preservation tend to<br />

disappear from view once the Realrationalität of ecological modernization sets in.<br />

Finally and perhaps most importantly, the M0 case rather clearly demonstrates a key<br />

difference between the EU’s (and the local Hungarian government’s) main eco-modernist<br />

discourse and its closest alternative, namely the more moderate reflexive modernization<br />

discourse prominent among many other international stakeholders (including most<br />

mainstream environmental NGOs and even parts of the EU itself): at minimum, the latter<br />

want to keep the precautionary promise alive. They would therefore advocate a more<br />

comprehensive, future-oriented risk assessment of all aspects of large-scale


399<br />

infrastructures, including the problematic, and difficult to asses, regional land use and<br />

mobility impacts which the eco-modernists perspective tends to underplay.<br />

In the end, it is not really possible for the international promoters of the M0 to<br />

interpret land use changes around the ring road as unforeseeable side-effects, e.g. an<br />

outgrowth of a dynamic local economy independent of international trends. Implicit in<br />

such an interpretation would be the admission that it was impossible to accurately assess<br />

all key costs and benefits of the planned infrastructure investments during the project<br />

identification stage. This, however, would in turn constitute an ex-post invalidation of<br />

whatever cost-benefit assessment was originally used to financially and economically<br />

justify the project in the first place.


400<br />

Printed on September 23, 2002<br />

Last revised on Sept 15, 2002<br />

PART IV: CONCLUSIONS &<br />

APPENDICES


401<br />

Printed on November 17, 2002<br />

Last revised on September 19, 2002<br />

CHAPTER TEN<br />

The Dilemmas of Planning for a<br />

Sustainable Europe<br />

.<br />

10.1 Planning, Sustainability and the “Contextual Discourse” Dilemma............... 402<br />

10.2 Summary of Previous Chapter Contents and Conclusions ............................. 405<br />

10.2.1 Theory-Building: What is a “Sustainable” Europe? ............................... 405<br />

10.2.2 Rhetoric: EU Transport Policy Discourses............................................. 407<br />

10.2.3 Realities: EU Transport Investments in Central Eastern Europe............ 410<br />

10.3 Cross-Cutting Conclusions on “Sustainable” Decision-Making .................... 414<br />

10.3.1 Normative Challenges: “Interpreting” Environmental Sustainability .... 414<br />

10.3.2 Legitimacy, Stakeholder Interests, and Mutually-Exclusive Objectives 415<br />

10.3.3 Higher Stakes Increase the Sophistication of Alternative Discourses.... 417<br />

10.3.4 Opportunistic Reasons for Adopting “Sustainability” Criteria............... 418<br />

10.3.5 Different Rationalities at Different Levels of Decision-Making ............ 419<br />

10.3.6 Different Rationalities at Different Times of Decision-Making............. 421<br />

10.3.7 “A Bottleneck is a Bottleneck is a …”? How Language Frames Policy 422<br />

10.3.8 The Role of Spatial Storylines and Leitbilder in Shaping Policy........... 424<br />

10.4 Suggestions for Better Transport Decision-Making in Europe....................... 426<br />

10.4.1 Taking Action on Strategic Environmental Assessment ........................ 427<br />

10.4.2 Bringing the Urban and Regional Dimensions Back In.......................... 427<br />

10.4.3 Integrated, Intermodal Thinking Instead of Bottleneck Fixing .............. 429<br />

10.4.4 Making the “Who Benefits” Question More Transparent ...................... 430<br />

10.4.5 Rethinking the Relationship between Traffic and Spatial Arguments.... 431<br />

10.4.6 Strengthen Local Planning and Land Use Regulations........................... 432<br />

10.5 Outlook: Suggestions for Further Research.................................................... 433


402<br />

10.1 Planning, Sustainability and the “Contextual Discourse” Dilemma<br />

Problems Worthy<br />

Of Attack<br />

Prove Their Worth<br />

By Hitting Back<br />

Piet Hein<br />

This study has covered a lot of ground, seeking to simultaneously make a<br />

contribution to such different fields as sustainable development, transport policy,<br />

discourse analysis, planning and policy development, infrastructure decision-making and<br />

European enlargement. Yet my overarching motivation for carrying out the research<br />

remained constant over the course of the entire study: My intention was to uncover the<br />

underlying “rationalities” of transport-related planning and policy-making processes in<br />

Europe. At the end of this quest, I remain – more than ever – convinced that detailed<br />

case study analyses of supra-national policy arrangements and of large-scale, multi-level<br />

infrastructure investment plans and projects continue to be the best way to unearth the<br />

central conflicting interests of planning and policy-making in (post-)modern societies.<br />

“Planning for a Sustainable Europe” remains an elusive concept, and especially<br />

so in the context of an ever eastward expanding European Union. In the transport sector,<br />

rhetorical commitments to transport sustainability only marginally influence the actual<br />

formulation of transport investments programs. Transport investment packages are<br />

instead mainly designed to satisfy varying sets of policy objectives related to economic<br />

development, infrastructure expansion, social and regional cohesion and enlargement.<br />

Environmental objectives are often treated as an afterthought, and to date, environmental<br />

impact assessments largely remain focused at the project level, thus only having a<br />

mitigatory, limiting impact on the planned investments rather than comprehensively


403<br />

challenging and re-evaluating planned investments from an integrated perspective (also<br />

see below).<br />

Overall, the decision-making processes surrounding EU transport infrastructure<br />

investments in the context of enlargement exhibit one recurring, contradictory tendency.<br />

This contradictory tendency, which I term the “contextual discourse” dilemma of<br />

contemporary planning and policy-making, has particular relevance for decision-making<br />

in contexts of multi-location politics as is the case with the European Union. This<br />

dilemma, which I consider the central analytical insight of my study, can be summarized<br />

as follows:<br />

On one hand, it is true that successful planning and policy-making is dependent<br />

on developing universally applicable, integrative guiding visions and storylines such as<br />

“sustainability” or “cohesion” to guide and legitimize decision-making. On the other<br />

hand, it is also true that such discursive concepts only become useful policy tools for<br />

decision-makers if they can be operationalized into concrete local/regional agendas<br />

resulting in specific investment choices in particular locales. In other words: in<br />

contemporary settings of global-regional interdependence, networked economies and<br />

multi-location politics, planners and policy-makers are increasingly challenged to justify<br />

their actions via the development of investment and decision-making rationales that<br />

might be simultaneously applicable both at the abstract-universal and at the concretelocal<br />

level. Yet the more grounded planning and policy-making discourses become in<br />

concrete local-regional contexts, the less universally applicable and the more conflictual<br />

and contradictory they become. Conversely, general discourses devoid of any<br />

applicability to local contexts are unlikely to gain widespread support.


404<br />

It is this constant process of rationalization and operationalization which is so<br />

crucially important in understanding the reasons for the obvious and ongoing<br />

discrepancies between the omnipresent environmental rhetoric of contemporary European<br />

societies (which is not limited to governments but also includes all other sectors<br />

including business and industry) and the ongoing environmentally unsustainable<br />

developments observable at the local level (e.g. suburbanization, sprawl, rising transport<br />

emissions, persistence of traffic accidents etc.). It is here, at the programmatic level,<br />

where key sustainability agendas are formulated, revised, adapted, coopted, corrupted, or<br />

possibly simply ignored. In the case of transport policy, “operationalizing” sustainability<br />

usually means developing criteria that either steer transport investment choices towards<br />

certain geographic locations (i.e. compact cities, non-ecologically-sensitive sites) or into<br />

certain “more sustainable” (i.e. less polluting, less energy-intensive, less fossil fuelintensive<br />

etc) transport systems. The latter can mean both, choosing between different<br />

modal alternatives, or choosing a more efficient model or system within the same mode.<br />

Clearly, the “contextual discourse” dilemma is a problem with several, sometimes<br />

interlocking dimensions.<br />

In the remainder of this concluding chapter I will a) once again briefly<br />

recapitulate the main contents and conclusions of the different parts of the study, b)<br />

present a variety of cross-cutting, summarizing conclusions, c) offer some concrete<br />

suggestions for improved transport-sector decision-making in Europe, and d) provide a<br />

short outlook for further research.


405<br />

10.2 Summary of Previous Chapter Contents and Conclusions<br />

My study was organized around six major propositions, which were introduced<br />

and contextualized in Chapter 1. They were not research hypotheses that demanded a<br />

strict verification, but rather served as guiding premises for the research. The<br />

propositions framed the investigative process in a delicate way, attempting to not<br />

preclude certain results while at the same time limiting the interpretive freedom in<br />

tackling such broad topics as sustainable spatial development and transport policy.<br />

Meanwhile, the study’s empirical focus on transport infrastructure investment decisionmaking<br />

in the particular context of EU enlargement to some extent limits the formulation<br />

of universal conclusions as far as either sustainability or transport policy is concerned.<br />

The results should nevertheless be seen as indicative of current trends. The key contents<br />

of the three study parts can be summarized as follows:<br />

10.2.1 Theory-Building: What is a “Sustainable” Europe?<br />

Part I was dedicated to some preliminary definitions, several introductory (meta-)<br />

theoretical considerations and the development of the middle-range concept of<br />

“discursive frameworks” for decision-making.<br />

Chapter 2 showed that neither<br />

development nor sustainability are easily definable concepts. Various, internationally<br />

sanctioned, normative definitions of sustainable development and of sustainable transport<br />

exist, but overall, the notion of “sustainable transport development” remains a relatively<br />

ill-defined concept. In particular, there is a continued ambiguity with regard to the<br />

assumed relationship between transport investments and economic development (i.e.<br />

growth). The supposedly harmonious relationship between the “three dimensions of


406<br />

sustainability” namely economy, environment, and equity, remains the most problematic<br />

aspect of the concept.<br />

Chapters 3 and 4 argued that EU transport sector decision-making is dominated<br />

by the discursive framework of ecological modernization. I defined a discursive<br />

framework as a theoretical approach consisting of an ensemble of underlying rationales<br />

and concepts that together form the intellectual backdrop for a set of policy responses and<br />

actions relating to a particular topic. I further defined ecological modernization as a<br />

modernist model of development that is relatively successful in integrating a variety of<br />

environmental and social concerns into its framework, but that nevertheless privileges<br />

competitiveness and economic growth over alternative development goals. Ecological<br />

modernization thus offers a win-win perspective that is best poised to incorporate wideranging<br />

environmental critiques into an overall, positive future vision of sustainable<br />

development. The alternative discursive frameworks of reflexive modernization and<br />

communicative rationality also offer comparatively optimistic outlooks, in the sense that<br />

they also fundamentally trust in the ability of modern capitalist democracies to readjust<br />

existing decision-making to adequately include the environmental dimension and for<br />

stakeholders to make enlightened, rational decisions about the future. The renunciation<br />

and the political economy frameworks are more skeptical. The renunciation perspective<br />

is eco-centric at its core and finds that nature is insufficiently respected and protected<br />

under capitalism. The political economy framework, by contrast, is more concerned<br />

about the social equity dimensions of the environmental problematique. Political<br />

economy scholars see decision-making in capitalist democracies as fundamentally


407<br />

contradictory and ultimately as a win-lose affair which is exploitative of both nature and<br />

of the weaker stakeholders.<br />

10.2.2 Rhetoric: EU Transport Policy Discourses<br />

Part II was dedicated to the analysis of EU transport policy “rhetoric.” The<br />

performed discourse analyses of key EU infrastructure policy documents and statements<br />

confirmed that growth and competitiveness considerations continue to win over<br />

redistributive and environmental aims. Most of the key EU documents referring to<br />

sustainable development and sustainable transport analyzed in Chapter 5 exhibited a clear<br />

tendency to adhere to the underlying rationale of ecological modernization which<br />

emphasizes “sustainable growth”. However, the text-oriented analysis in this chapter<br />

also showed that the EU does not always strictly follow the discursive framework of<br />

ecological modernization in its formulation of policy objectives. Instead, the EU borrows<br />

rather freely from a variety of rationales, be this the result of intentional strategizing or<br />

unintentional multifaceted rationalizing on the part of EU decision-makers. So in the<br />

end, EU policy statements on sustainable transport are biased in favor of ecological<br />

modernization in an inconsistent way. Quite predictably, statements coming out of the<br />

DG Environment are often more environmentally ambitious than formulations coming<br />

from DG Transport and Energy. Some formulations are openly contradictory. So the<br />

accusation that the EU simply “disregards the environment” is too simple. The EU is<br />

simply not binding itself to a more “radical” interpretation of sustainable transport the<br />

way that political economists or environmentalists do. Measured within its own<br />

discursive framework, the EU obviously appears less hypocritical than seen from without.


408<br />

Chapter 6 departed from the more text-oriented discourse analysis in Chapter 5<br />

and took a more thematic approach. Three overarching guiding visions (Leitbilder) used<br />

in EU decision-making were identified: On one hand, the EU is always torn between the<br />

twin forces of “integration” (deepening) and “expansion” (widening). On the other hand,<br />

the new mandate of “sustainability” has brought an additional dimension to EU decisionmaking.<br />

None of these three general Leitbilder are specific enough to generate detailed<br />

policies and plans in the transport sector. Yet there are in fact several different<br />

identifiable sub-discourses influencing EU transport infrastructure investment rationales.<br />

In analyzing these sub-discourses, I reverted to a discourse analytical concept used by<br />

Maarten Hajer in his own 1995 study on ecological modernization and the policy process,<br />

namely the concept of “storylines.” Put very simply, storylines are generative narratives<br />

that give meaning to specific physical or social phenomena, and they can induce political<br />

change and reorder understandings. Most importantly, “finding the appropriate storyline<br />

becomes an important form of agency” (Hajer 1996:56). I adapted this concept to the<br />

particular case of EU transport infrastructure decision-making, and identified four<br />

different “spatial storylines” justifying EU transport infrastructure investments in the<br />

1990s: “cohesion,” “polycentricity,” “missing links,” and “bottlenecks.” I showed how<br />

these different storylines cluster knowledge, position different stakeholders and,<br />

ultimately, create different coalitions for decision-making. The “cohesion” and<br />

“polycentricity” storylines are partially complementary and mutually reinforcing, as are<br />

the “missing links” and “bottlenecks” storylines. Yet the two pairs<br />

“cohesion/polycentricity” and “missing links/bottlenecks” end up privileging almost<br />

opposite types of investments. Meanwhile, the “cohesion” and “polycentricity”


409<br />

storylines are closely aligned with policies that fall within the competency of DG Regio,<br />

while the “missing links” and “bottlenecks” storylines are more closely aligned with<br />

policies coming out of the DG TREN. I also showed that as far as actual transport<br />

investment plans and programs – and especially the Trans-European Networks - are<br />

concerned, discourses related to “missing links” and “bottlenecks” continue to win over<br />

alternative storylines.<br />

Almost by definition, the EU’s high-priority “backbone networks” located inside<br />

the Blue Banana core of Europe and along the ten Pan-European Helsinki corridors<br />

privilege connections between large cities. Contrary to the EU objective of achieving<br />

greater social and economic cohesion, this means losers are scattered in peripheral and<br />

bypass locations, and, according to the many experts, also at the weaker of the two<br />

corridor ends. This latter point becomes particularly important when we consider the<br />

EU’s ambitions to extend the TENs into Central and Eastern Europe. EU transport policy<br />

thus remains deeply conflicted and contested, and EU transport sector investments<br />

continue to have to satisfy different aims related to growth, competitiveness, cohesion<br />

and sustainability. Environmental concerns often take a back seat to mainstream<br />

economic development interests, and the politically most influential core regions<br />

continue to be able to attract a significant amount of infrastructure funding at the expense<br />

of less economically advanced peripheral areas. I also concluded that the EU’s TEN<br />

priority projects fundamentally contradict cohesion goals by concentrating high-profile<br />

transport investments in already privileged areas.


410<br />

10.2.3 Realities: EU Transport Investments in Central Eastern Europe<br />

Taking the above described contradictions and biases in EU transport investment<br />

rationales as their starting point, Part III analyzed EU transport infrastructure decisionmaking<br />

in the particular context of Eastern enlargement. The key objective of this<br />

“realities” part of the study was to identify to what degree conflicts of interests<br />

surrounding particular infrastructure investments could be related back to different<br />

underlying investment rationales. The ensuing analysis of transport sector decisionmaking<br />

in CEE of course had to be seen in context with the collapse of Communism in<br />

that region, and with the transformation from centrally planned to market economies.<br />

Socialism’s legacy of non-market infrastructures, land-uses and (intra-urban) population<br />

densities included large, publicly-owned and -subsidized public transit systems on one<br />

hand, and road networks which were comparatively modest in size and relatively<br />

undifferentiated on the other. Significant backlogs in infrastructure and equipment<br />

maintenance were built up during the 1980s. National and local governments now<br />

struggle with rising levels of traffic congestion, noise, accidents, and pollution in<br />

urbanized areas, and with ill-maintained and inappropriate urban, regional and longdistance<br />

transport infrastructure systems. Under such conditions, the pursuit of<br />

sustainable transport infrastructure decision-making appeared a particularly daunting<br />

task. Additionally, I also anticipated that shifting political powers and insufficiently or<br />

inefficiently distributed decisional responsibilities at the national level would further<br />

exacerbate the challenge of multi-location policy-making for the EU stakeholders.<br />

In Chapter 7, I concentrated on the Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment<br />

(TINA) for CEE. In the end, this process of drawing-up and calculating the costs for an


411<br />

internationally-linked priority transport network for the CEE region displayed quite a<br />

different dynamic from the type of targeted “missing links” industry pet project lobbing<br />

that went on during the development of the TEN priority projects. Both the Helsinki<br />

Corridor and the TINA processes were steered by the EU Commission under the critical<br />

eyes of the national governments, and without any discernable prevailing influence of<br />

either private sector interests or civil society. Hence, I had to somewhat reconsider my<br />

“Decisional-Power” proposition which had assumed a combined predominance of both<br />

national and multi-national corporate interests in transport decision-making both inside<br />

and outside the EU. Interestingly, while from the point of view of the Commission, the<br />

TINA process was an attempt to politically and scientifically justify their foreseen<br />

emphasis on international corridors with regard to future ISPA grant funding, from the<br />

point of view of the participating CEE governments, TINA was their best chance to<br />

“amend” the Helsinki Corridor commitments and to make a case for the inclusion of<br />

additional national priority networks. Once agreed upon, the corridor backbone<br />

prioritizations proved hard to undo.<br />

In Chapter 8, I analyzed the first two years of EU pre-accession grant-making for<br />

transport infrastructure investments under the EU ISPA (Instrument for Structural<br />

Policies for Pre-Accession) program in two of the most advanced candidate countries,<br />

Poland and Hungary. The experience of the first two years showed that the ISPA<br />

National Strategies played very different roles in the two case study countries in terms of<br />

re-organizing national transport policies. While Polish official(s) took the writing of the<br />

ISPA national strategy document as a welcome opportunity to force their own<br />

government to develop a medium to long-term, mode-specific list of priorities in the


412<br />

transport sector and to commit to a multi-year strategy (thereby making Polish transport<br />

policy more future-oriented, internally consistent and better integrated across sectors),<br />

Hungarian officials saw the writing of the strategy mostly as a necessary document to<br />

receive supplementary financial aid from Brussels. In Hungary, grave violations of<br />

international procurement rules in the national expressway program resulted in road<br />

sector projects being rejected by the ISPA management committee, but the government<br />

simply rearranged their ISPA strategy and excluded the problematic motorways from the<br />

list. The highly unusual 90% imbalance in favor of rail in the Hungarian ISPA program<br />

therefore had to be seen in the context of a continued bias in favor of road projects both<br />

in terms of national government funding and IFI loans. Railway projects in CEE<br />

typically require a broader sectoral approach involving difficult questions of overall<br />

restructuring, and are frequently more complicated to justify in terms of strict financial<br />

and economic rates of return. However, contrary to previous EU-led funding in the<br />

region, ISPA allocations have so far been rather evenly balanced between the road and<br />

the rail sectors, with over half of all grants going to rail projects. Overall, program<br />

decisions seemed still rather strongly influenced by the EU’s DG Regio. In both cases,<br />

DG Regio placed a near exclusive emphasis on funding major corridors facing the EU<br />

borders and was reluctant to consider non-Helsinki corridor TINA network stretches for<br />

initial funding. In the end, the EU favors an accession-oriented focus on international<br />

links without necessarily relying on existing traffic flows or current market demand. Key<br />

international transport experts find that this exclusive focus on international links is<br />

misguided.


413<br />

In Chapter 9, I looked at the M0 ring road around Budapest as an interesting case<br />

study example of a key infrastructure node with important, partially interlocking local,<br />

regional, national and international transport functions. I applied my typology of<br />

discursive frameworks for “sustainable” transport policy decision-making to a concrete<br />

case study and compared how the overarching themes, key concepts and policy proposals<br />

of the five different discursive frameworks were reflected in the local controversies over<br />

a large-scale infrastructure. The M0 case showed that concerns such as public<br />

accountability, participatory democracy, mediation of locational conflict, and<br />

environmental preservation tended to disappear from view once the Realrationalität of<br />

ecological modernization set in. Additionally, the M0 case also demonstrated a key<br />

difference between the EU’s (and the local Hungarian government’s) main eco-modernist<br />

discourse and its closest alternative, namely the more moderate reflexive modernization<br />

discourse: at minimum, the latter keeps the promise of the “precautionary principle”<br />

alive. Proponents of the reflexive approach would therefore advocate a more<br />

comprehensive, future-oriented risk assessment of all aspects of large-scale<br />

infrastructures, including the problematic, and difficult to asses, regional land use and<br />

mobility impacts.<br />

In the end, the ring road chapter validated the “Local Impacts” proposition, which<br />

assumed that the types of “ecological modernization” investment rationales favored by<br />

the EU would tend to underestimate the negative local impacts of large-scale<br />

infrastructures. The chapter also showed how each of the four alternative discursive<br />

frameworks added an important dimension to the overall problem. Interestingly, not all<br />

of them can be easily adequately addressed within the current decision-making system.


414<br />

10.3 Cross-Cutting Conclusions on “Sustainable” Decision-Making<br />

10.3.1 Normative Challenges: “Interpreting” Environmental Sustainability<br />

Many of the more daring, more radical and more original writings on transport<br />

and environment to date are heavily influenced by post-modern ideas. They reject<br />

mainstream environmental discourses as “totalizing” and instead advocate antiestablishment<br />

ideals of situated, bottom-up knowledge and resource exchange. By and<br />

large, this is good news for environmentally-minded planners and policy makers. The<br />

bad news is that it is more difficult to establish normative meanings for abstract terms in<br />

a postmodern world of multiple discourses. An ironic, regrettable dynamic has emerged<br />

where many postmodern environmentalists simultaneously argue for an acceptation of<br />

multiple, equally-valid viewpoints on “environment” and “development” on one hand<br />

and a rejection of mainstream, eco-managerial approaches to sustainable (transport)<br />

development on the other. Many avowed post-modernists thus in fact harbor rather<br />

normative views on sustainable development, typically demanding the increased<br />

protection of natural habitats, decreased motorization and tighter land use controls.<br />

While I am very sympathetic to the idea of stricter environmental and development<br />

norms, such an approach seems rather contradictory to me. One needs to try to be<br />

consistent at the meta-theoretical, the theoretical and the prescriptive levels. Ensuing<br />

definitions of transport and land use sustainability should offer as little room for<br />

interpretation as possible. In my view, this underlines the need for empirically grounded<br />

definitions of environmental sustainability, both at the local and at the European (or<br />

global) level. Multiple viewpoints may be fruitful, but we have to establish certain


415<br />

guideposts for interpreting reality or else risk arbitrariness. Most importantly, we simply<br />

cannot afford to forego judgment on the negative consequences of our current mode of<br />

development. And one need not be an orthodox Marxist or an anti-modern ecologist to<br />

understand that the consumption of finite natural resources, the loss of natural habitats<br />

and the negative environmental externalities affecting humans across Europe, and across<br />

the globe, are all largely a consequence of the integral developmental needs of modern<br />

capitalism.<br />

10.3.2 Legitimacy, Stakeholder Interests, and Mutually-Exclusive Objectives<br />

The impossibility of developing universally acceptable discourses also has a<br />

structuralist dimension, bringing us back to Foglesong’s capitalist-democracy<br />

contradiction. In the end, the EU seeks to adopt mutually exclusive development<br />

objectives (e.g. “cohesion” vs. “global competitiveness,” “environmental sustainability”<br />

vs. “accelerated industrial growth”) in order to assuage adversarial constituents. Similar<br />

to the national level, the EU’s legitimacy as a supra-national political institution is based<br />

on Western conceptions of democracy and public interest politics operating under an<br />

economic system of welfare capitalism. So like its member states, the EU faces the triple<br />

challenge of successfully safeguarding market-oriented institutional structures that<br />

encourage profit-making entrepreneurialism, guaranteeing the provision of the public<br />

infrastructures necessary for such activity, and lastly, shielding its citizens and the<br />

environment from the all-too-abusive tendencies of the system by performing<br />

redistributive welfare and environmental protection functions. History-making decisions<br />

concerning the Single Market and the (Treaty on) European Union were designed to


416<br />

address the first of these challenges – remember that the EU’s original raison d’être was<br />

economic, not political integration – while the decision on Trans-European Networks<br />

showed that public infrastructure provision is increasingly being coordinated at the supranational<br />

level. Meanwhile, the Cohesion Fund, the Environmental Action Programs and,<br />

most recently, the Sustainable Development Strategy are all expressions of the<br />

redistributive and mitigating functions that the EU also has to perform in order to not lose<br />

its legitimacy as a supra-national institution. So seen from a structuralist (Marxist)<br />

perspective, the main reason for the EU to provide structural funds to disadvantaged and<br />

peripheral regions and adopt the precautionary principle for environmental management<br />

is the continued assurance of the institutional prerequisites for capital accumulation for<br />

future generations. Yet in my view, such an interpretation is overly cynical,<br />

deterministic, and gives the EU too much credit for successfully anticipating the<br />

structural needs of organized capitalism in a globalized economy. More importantly, my<br />

study showed that such a “black box” perspective of the EU as a unitary decision-maker<br />

acting – possibly even unbeknownst to itself – more or less at the services of dominant<br />

economic agents underestimates the extent to which different decision-making arms<br />

within the EU exhibit fundamental differences in their outlook on matters of environment<br />

and development. Not only does there exist a significant range of approaches within the<br />

EU’s dominant discursive framework of ecological modernization, but many stakeholders<br />

inside the EU are even poised to adopt alternative decision-making rationales favoring<br />

much more environmentally, socially and procedurally demanding interpretations of<br />

“sustainability” (e.g. DG Environment officials, Green and socialist parliamentarians, the<br />

EU Ombudsman). Structuralist perspectives provide convenient, often sweeping, ex-post


417<br />

explanations of why “in the end, the ruling class always wins.” But we tend to learn too<br />

little about the decision-making powers of individual agents along the way. To some<br />

degree, this criticism can also be transferred to Foucauldian discourse analyses. 1<br />

This is<br />

why I supplemented my initial, more discourse-analytical propositions with several<br />

propositions that explicitly targeted on relative power relationships as well as nationally<br />

and locally-specific outcomes.<br />

10.3.3 Higher Stakes Increase the Sophistication of Alternative Discourses<br />

Ever since the EU’s decision to co-fund the TENs, transport infrastructure<br />

funding has become a hotly debated political issue even at the Pan-European level.<br />

Somewhat counter-intuitively – and contrary to previous scholars of EU transport<br />

infrastructure plans (e.g Ross 1998) – I find that this has ultimately increased the<br />

opportunities for sustainable transport decision-making, albeit only indirectly and with a<br />

time-lag. On one hand, it is true that the higher the stakes are, the more likely<br />

accommodating, universally comfortable “sustainability” discourses will give way to<br />

(self-interested) power play politics, and the TENs have in fact revealed the continued<br />

political muscle of the European pro-growth players. Yet on the other hand, the<br />

heightened politicization of transport infrastructure investment struggles has also led to<br />

an increasingly sophisticated articulation of alternative development approaches based on<br />

equity, environmental and procedural concerns. Needless to say, however, that unless<br />

1 Remember, for example, that Maarten Hajer’s “discourse coalitions,” were not defined as a group of<br />

individual decision-makers but “as the ensemble of (1) a set of storylines; (2) the actors who utter these<br />

storylines; and (3) the practices in which this discursive activity is based,” i.e. a strange amalgam of people,<br />

their practices and their discourses. So by design, the concept puts little emphasis on individual agency.<br />

Also see the long footnote 9 in Chapter 6.


418<br />

such alternative visions are then given political and institutional “teeth,” the actual impact<br />

of such alternative discourses remains limited.<br />

10.3.4 Opportunistic Reasons for Adopting “Sustainability” Criteria<br />

When it comes to preserving and expanding their own decision-making powers,<br />

local authorities in the European Union typically like to remind Eurocrats in Brussels of<br />

the concept of subsidiarity which the EU has adopted as its fundamental governing<br />

principle. However, parallel to the generally observed and much discussed Europeanwide<br />

devolution of power in favor local and regional authorities, the EU has nevertheless<br />

expanded its reach in several key areas of planning and decision-making. As we have<br />

seen, the transport sector is one area where EU involvement in planning and policymaking<br />

has been most noticeable during the last decade, with EU loans and grant funds<br />

for Pan-European transport priority projects already running in the billions of Euros, and<br />

with much more to follow in the near future. Not surprisingly, whenever they need to<br />

attract Pan-European funds for locally important infrastructure projects, urban and<br />

regional authorities’ criticism of Brussels’ supposed over-involvement in planning<br />

matters turns into a much more cajoling attitude aimed at accessing EU coffers. In the<br />

case of the Central European candidate countries, the EU’s opportunity to influence longterm<br />

spatial development through the co-financing of key transport-infrastructures is even<br />

greater insofar as those countries have much fewer financial resources themselves and a<br />

much weaker bargaining position due to their applicant status. So in theory, the prospect<br />

of Eastern enlargement provides current EU member states with a historic opportunity to<br />

deeply shape both the rhetoric and the reality of transport and land use policy in CEE.


419<br />

How far this leverage is then pro-actively and positively used in actual infrastructure<br />

support programs is another matter that is likely to vary on a case-by-case basis. My<br />

CEE examples show that the Commission is likely to be strict about procedural issues<br />

such as open tenders and compliance with basic EIA rules, yet less inclined to raise the<br />

bar any further on matters concerning strategic environmental assessments or the<br />

integration of longer-term land-use impacts into transport decision-making.<br />

10.3.5 Different Rationalities at Different Levels of Decision-Making<br />

Apart from the persistence of competing interests and investment rationales, there<br />

is an additional, cross-cutting explanation for the apparent inconsistencies in EU<br />

decision-making: different decision-making rationalities apply at different levels of<br />

decision-making. This insight brings us back to Peterson and Bomberg’s (1999) useful<br />

distinction of three different rationalities for history-making, policy-setting and policyshaping<br />

types of decision (see table 1.1 in the introductory chapter). As a particular<br />

policy issue is handed through various decision-making ranks, super-systemic policy<br />

goals get transformed, and sometimes even perverted, at the systemic or sub-systemic<br />

level. The policy-making process for Pan-European transport infrastructures is a salient<br />

example of this. The decision to consider CEECs as potential candidates for enlargement<br />

was certainly a history-making event. The subsequent history-making / policy-setting<br />

agreement on ten Pan-European transport priority corridors to connect Europe was made<br />

by national ministers of transport in a bargaining mode that was predominantly<br />

intergovernmental and with a rationality that might best be characterized as<br />

(geo)political. So actual traffic flows along the corridors were not very important, yet


420<br />

including the capitals of all participating countries in the overall corridor list was. In<br />

terms of storylines, the “missing links” argument was thus employed with a prevailing<br />

emphasis on “linking Europe(an capitals).” The subsequent TINA exercise, by contrast,<br />

was a process located somewhere between a policy-setting and a policy-shaping decision<br />

dominated by senior officials of national ministries and by EU Commission<br />

representatives. Here, decision-making rationalities were more political-technocratic<br />

and, at least to some degree, consensus-oriented. In this context of inter-institutional<br />

bargaining, criteria which were ostensibly less political but more “scientific,” such as<br />

traffic forecasts and cost estimates, increasingly formed the basis for decision-making,<br />

alongside the basic criterion of achieving international connectivity between national<br />

networks. “Missing links” now primarily meant “missing infrastructure links across<br />

national borders.” Interestingly, the later ISPA national transport programs, which were<br />

to take the TINA exercise as their basis for selecting individual projects, were then not<br />

lower-level (sub-systemic), merely policy-shaping types of decision following TINA, but<br />

rather new policy-setting decisions. Hence ISPA, like TINA, was more characterized by<br />

inter-institutional bargaining than by resource exchange. In particular, decisions<br />

regarding the national ISPA strategies were more strongly influenced by (national-level)<br />

political rationalities than by technocratic or consensual considerations. Consequently,<br />

grants were also requested for national ISPA “priority” projects which had played no<br />

significant role at the Pan-European transport ministers conferences or in the TINA<br />

process (e.g. regional airports, axle load strengthening along secondary roads).<br />

Meanwhile, some Commission representatives in charge of implementing ISPA at DG<br />

Regio explicitly rejected the previous, DG TREN-led TINA input as a relevant basis for


421<br />

decision-making, and instead re-emphasized the Helsinki corridors. Others were, and<br />

still are, mostly concerned about the maturity of individual projects. The ongoing ISPA<br />

program is therefore faced with bringing together rather different rationales at the<br />

national and at the EU level. And at least for the recipient national governments,<br />

“missing links” of course mostly means “missing links (and nodes) within our national<br />

territory.”<br />

So once again, we see how discourses related to “missing links” serve to satisfy<br />

different development goals. Conversely, this example also once again explains the great<br />

appeal of the “missing links” storyline: unlike many other discursive concepts, the<br />

imagery of “missing links” can be very conveniently applied both at the abstractuniversal<br />

and at the locally specific level. Moreover, the term “missing” conveniently<br />

fosters a pro-investment attitude by implying that all links are in fact needed and should<br />

be “found.” Suddenly, the issue is not a potentially controversial choice between<br />

different infrastructure alternatives, but merely an agreement on different priorities.<br />

10.3.6 Different Rationalities at Different Times of Decision-Making<br />

There is also a temporal dimension to decision-making. Infrastructure needs<br />

change over time, and these needs change more rapidly in the Central European context<br />

of economic transition than in the mature economies of Western Europe. As the sociospatial<br />

transition to market-oriented, post-Fordist production and consumption patterns<br />

progresses, new winning and losing regions and cities constantly emerge, thereby<br />

continually rearranging inter-regional traffic flows. The general expectation that new<br />

“missing links” and “bottlenecks” would primarily emerge along the Western borders,


422<br />

while previous “priority connections” in the East (particularly freight rail) would<br />

increasingly become obsolete has generally proved to be correct. Nevertheless, traffic<br />

volumes along certain links have exceeded expectations, while they have been lagging<br />

along others. In Hungary, the end of violent conflict in Former Yugoslavia has brought<br />

particularly dramatic changes.<br />

Additionally, infrastructure priorities, of course, also change over time without<br />

any real changes in traffic flows. National infrastructure priority lists typically get<br />

rearranged whenever national elections bring about political change in the government.<br />

This is simply due to the fact that different political parties cater to different national<br />

constituencies – which brings us back to the issue of legitimacy of interests and political<br />

support (see above).<br />

10.3.7 “A Bottleneck is a Bottleneck is a …”? How Language Frames Policy<br />

As the “missing links” example shows, employing the “right” kinds of images,<br />

metaphors or storylines within a particular policy discourse becomes an important form<br />

of agency. The rhetorical framing of a particular policy problem to some extent already<br />

limits the range of possible solutions which are allowed into the debate. In common<br />

usage, Gertrud Stein’s famous phrase from Sacred Emily, “A rose is a rose is a rose” is<br />

typically intended to mean that, when all is said and done, a thing is what it is.<br />

Poststructuralists take issue with this even in the case of tangible objects such as flowers.<br />

Yet even without having to take social constructivist viewpoints to their linguistic limits,<br />

it seems clear from my study that such “object objectification” is particularly<br />

unacceptable when it comes to selecting and defining abstract terms such as “cohesion”


423<br />

or “congestion.” This is why all discourse theoretical approaches, no matter whether they<br />

feel more inspired by Jürgen Habermas or Michel Foucault, deserve credit for unveiling<br />

the mask of “objective rationality” behind which dominant transport and planning<br />

approaches hide.<br />

Of course, we cannot analytically deconstruct our way out of congestion, but<br />

discourse analysis can help us understand why policy approaches might focus on<br />

“congestion” in the first place, and how metaphorical terms such as “bottlenecks” gain<br />

meaning and widespread currency. Richard Willson (2001:2) powerfully underscores<br />

this fundamental point:<br />

Are not measures of vehicle flows, levels of service or cost effectiveness robust<br />

representations of reality? Gridlock is gridlock, right? For planning, however,<br />

gridlock is not gridlock until we have defined it as a problem and decided to do<br />

something to address it. Transportation plans depend on what gridlock means, and<br />

establishing meaning is an inherently social and linguistically based process. The way<br />

that transportation planners use language – understanding certain ideas and values and<br />

excluding others, hearing some things and not hearing others, and defining roles for<br />

themselves, their organizations, decision makers and the public – shapes knowledge,<br />

public participation, problem definition, process design and negotiation, and the<br />

outcome of planning.<br />

In the case of European Union transport policy making and planning, Eurocrats in<br />

the Transport and Energy Directorate recently forcefully resuscitated the nightmarish<br />

vision of gridlock in favor of many other possible imagined futures, thereby also focusing<br />

their views much more on the likely outcomes than on the underlying causes of current<br />

transport system inefficiencies. “Safety” and “emissions” are other frequently heard<br />

worries. The entirety of Europe’s predominantly road- and motor-vehicles-based<br />

transport system is rarely questioned, however, since it is seen as providing the<br />

foundation for European economic competitiveness.


424<br />

10.3.8 The Role of Spatial Storylines and Leitbilder in Shaping Policy<br />

Given the need to develop unifying concepts for decision-making, the question of<br />

the integrating power of spatial storylines and metaphors suggests itself. If language<br />

frames policy, does this also mean spatial storylines and Leitbilder in turn re-shape<br />

spatial realities? I am more skeptical here. I believe that my analysis of spatial storylines<br />

for transport investments suggests that their usefulness as instruments for spatial planning<br />

is ultimately more limited than planners like to believe. First of all, it seems that<br />

Leitbilder and storylines need to have some empirical basis in reality in order to<br />

successfully induce policy-change. A related insight is that the structural premises for the<br />

successful spatial de-concentration or re-organization of socio-economic activity change<br />

over time, resulting in different prospects for different spatial visions at different times.<br />

Rather befitting for the structural premises of the post-Fordist city in the electronic<br />

information age, spatial catchphrases such as “polycentricity” or “network society” have<br />

gained currency in planning and policy-making circles in recent years. However, finding<br />

appropriate spatial terms to express changes and shifts in the real-existing spatial<br />

structures is but a first step. Proclaiming the rise of the “Zwischenstadt” (Sieverts 1998)<br />

or the “Regional City” (Calthorpe and Fulton 2001) alone will not limit the advent of<br />

sprawl and suburbanization. Simply finding a more benign-sounding term for an ongoing<br />

spatial trend does not make it any less environmentally harmful. The same is true for the<br />

even more ambitious re-issuance of the “Compact city” ideal, i.e. a mere proclamation of<br />

the antidote. Likewise will the propagation of a simple-yet-clever drawing of a<br />

polycentric “European grape” in and of itself not be able to counteract a further


425<br />

concentration of economic activity along the “Blue banana” core of Western Europe, and<br />

no Cohesion fund will actually enhance spatial cohesion across European territories if it<br />

primarily directs funds towards national-level priority links between already privileged,<br />

better-off agglomerations.<br />

I agree that new, action-oriented policy consensuses best emerge via ongoing<br />

debates over negative and positive connotations of certain spatial terms, i.e. via discourse,<br />

but these debates must be grounded in empirical spatial analyses. Northern and Western<br />

European countries have a stronger tradition of using spatial images to back spatial policy<br />

proposals than Southern and Eastern European ones. Prominent examples are the “Green<br />

Heart” (groenehart) policy of the Dutch Randstad region, the Leitbild of “decentralized<br />

concentration” (Dezentrale Konzentration) in <strong>Berlin</strong>-Brandenburg in Germany, or, last<br />

but not least, the “polycentricity” concept of the European Spatial Development<br />

Perspective (which was chiefly promoted by Germany and a few other West European<br />

countries). The experience of the Netherlands, and, to a more limited extent, Germany,<br />

shows that if formulated with strong political backing and translated into concrete dos<br />

and don’ts for local land use and transport investments, such spatial images may be able<br />

to redirect spatial activity at the metropolitan level. At the present time, however, there<br />

are no such efforts discernable at the metropolitan level in the transition countries. Local<br />

pressures on greenfield development still overwhelm nascent regional planning efforts,<br />

and road infrastructure investments are easily instrumentalized for greenfield<br />

development purposes. In such contexts, spatial storylines such as “polycentricity” have<br />

little prescriptive value at the local level. The integrating power of spatial storylines<br />

seems further limited in Poland and Hungary because strategic geopolitical interests favor


426<br />

certain transport infrastructures over others, and because there is no final national<br />

consensus over investment priorities among different regional players.<br />

10.4 Suggestions for Better Transport Decision-Making in Europe<br />

Taking the above dilemmas and challenges into account, how might we conceive<br />

of an improved system of transport infrastructure decision-making in Europe? It would<br />

be presumptuous to attempt to answer such a comprehensive question in a few<br />

concluding paragraphs. Moreover, as I have insisted again and again throughout this<br />

study, where one sets the priorities depends on the discursive framework one adheres to.<br />

“Better” means “more competitive” to some, “more equitable” to others and “less<br />

polluting” to many others. Better can also mean “more integrated,” “more transparent”<br />

or simply “safer.” Unfortunately, we can rarely have it all at the same time.<br />

In the following sections, I take a rather pragmatic approach. Instead of<br />

proposing to revolutionize the system, I will confine myself to addressing a few select,<br />

relatively concrete issues which emerge from my case study research. None of these<br />

suggestions fundamentally challenge the EU’s overarching approach of ecological<br />

modernization, and all of them are supported by existing EU rhetoric. At most, they<br />

demand that the EU and its current and future member states become somewhat more<br />

“reflexive” in their approaches to ecological modernization, and begin to better deliver on<br />

their already given promise of minimizing the future environmental impacts of transport<br />

and land use systems.


427<br />

10.4.1 Taking Action on Strategic Environmental Assessment<br />

Recently restated rhetorical commitments to perform strategic environmental<br />

assessments (SEAs) on major transport infrastructure investment packages (see CEC<br />

2001d:45) remain largely unimplemented, although there are notable exceptions<br />

(especially with regard to current plans to perform SEAs along the Via Baltica corridor).<br />

Unfortunately, since decisions on the TENs and their priority projects as well as decisions<br />

on the TINA and the Pan-European Corridors were largely a fait accompli by the late<br />

1990s, the calls for SEAs on the TENs and the TINA network were already somewhat<br />

obsolete at the time they first became official EU rhetoric. 2<br />

Nevertheless, environmental<br />

advocates continue to argue that SEAs should be performed of the Pan-European<br />

transport plans. Since the Commission itself has already developed the necessary<br />

methodologies, this is simply a matter of mustering the political will and taking action.<br />

As recently as May 2002, the European Parliament took a plenary vote deciding that the<br />

TENs and the TINA network should be subjected to SEAs. So far, transport ministers<br />

and the Commission have not followed this lead. It is time they did.<br />

10.4.2 Bringing the Urban and Regional Dimensions Back In<br />

Transport infrastructure funding entails win-win, but also win-lose relationships<br />

between different geographical scales. In the “realities” part of my study, I agreed with<br />

key international experts that the strong concentration of grant funds onto major<br />

international corridors is problematic from the point of view of the recipient countries.<br />

2 In the cases where SEA methodologies were applied, they were only performed on individual corridors,<br />

but never on entire networks. Most importantly, they were never applied on the entirety of Pan-European<br />

transport policies and plans. The DG TRENs Manual on SEA in Transport was only completed in 1999.<br />

For additional information on SEAs in the context of environmental and transport decision-making, see the<br />

materials provided by DG Environment under http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/eia/sea-support.htm .


428<br />

From a regional development perspective, the international investment focus is likely to<br />

exacerbate the problematic trend of increasing economic disparity between the prospering<br />

western border regions and the more struggling regions facing the eastern border. More<br />

importantly, EU grant funding ignores what is probably the most important transport<br />

infrastructure investment need in the CEE countries, namely urban transport. ISPA grant<br />

funds cannot be used for urban transit projects, although most ailing public transport<br />

systems and skyrocketing motorization pose major challenges to CEE cities. Given that<br />

major CEE capitals like Budapest, Warsaw or Prague are the most important sites for<br />

economic and social production in the region, it seems particularly troublesome that the<br />

EU transport funds have no mechanism for lending for urban and regional transport.<br />

Public transport investments are equally crucial in secondary cities.<br />

The argument that EU grant funding for urban transport projects is precluded due<br />

to the subsidarity principle remains an important objection. However, the problem with<br />

this line of argument is that there is in fact one type of urban transport infrastructure<br />

which is eligible for EU grant funding under ISPA and PHARE, and that is ring roads<br />

and bypasses around major towns. So in the end, there is a de-facto built-in road bias in<br />

EU lending. While these road-based new construction projects receive precious EU grant<br />

funding, the modernization of CEE’s struggling, mostly rail-based urban transit systems,<br />

which are often directly competing for suburban ridership along ring road alignments, are<br />

left to the countries, or even worse: the municipalities themselves. In Chapter 8, I<br />

showed that the fear that ISPA’s anti-urban bias is ultimately contra-productive for<br />

developing sustainable transport systems in the CEE candidate countries is something


429<br />

brought forward not only by many of the environmental NGOs working on these issues,<br />

but also by key policy experts both in Brussels and in the CEE countries themselves.<br />

On a pragmatic level, the Commission could strive to creatively address this bias<br />

either by revising the ISPA rules and regulations or by attempting to provide Phare<br />

“regional development” grants for urban transit systems. More generally, the EU should<br />

strive to play a more modally-balanced and possibly more involved role in urban<br />

transport matters. The finalization of the long-promised Green Paper on Urban Transport<br />

would be a useful first step in this direction.<br />

10.4.3 Integrated, Intermodal Thinking Instead of Bottleneck Fixing<br />

Refocusing attention on urban transport problems should not mean sticking with<br />

the kind of “bottleneck” rhetoric championed in the EU’s new White Paper on Transport<br />

(Commission of the European Communities 2001f), because, somewhat ironically, the<br />

urban dimension is already over-emphasized when it comes to justifying highway<br />

expansions. Mateo Turro (1999:27) concisely summarized the problem as follows:<br />

Most Motorway traffic in Europe is of local and regional character. A purely demandled<br />

planning exercise would not pay enough attention to long- distance and,<br />

particularly, international travel, so a large share of the investment in motorways<br />

would be directed, as in the past, to relieving congestion created by short-distance<br />

traffic. Although this traffic created bottlenecks that affect transport crossing<br />

congested urban areas, the long-term solution for interurban traffic can only be found<br />

in a wider geographical context.<br />

In other words: Motorway traffic problems that are mostly home-made (i.e.<br />

created at the local level) sometimes receive an unfair boon of national and international<br />

funding simply because the congested areas happen to also affect international or national<br />

travel. This scenario is confirmed by the Budapest ring road which according to experts


430<br />

carries 90% local traffic. Yet curing the congestive symptoms of an unhealthy transport<br />

system through highway expansion at the local level not only under-appreciates the<br />

regional and international dimensions of travel, but it also ignores preferable approaches<br />

to fixing transport problems in general. Even the EU’s recent emphasis on congestion<br />

pricing only provides a partial, limited response. The problem of over-reliance on<br />

automobile and truck travel needs to be addressed from a larger, long-term perspective<br />

that includes the integration of land-use planning, demand management and the provision<br />

of clear modal alternatives for passenger travel and freight. The mantra of integrated,<br />

inter-modal network planning has been repeated by EU transport experts for decades, and<br />

almost all EU-funded research on transport and land-use planning treats it as a foregone<br />

conclusion. Nevertheless, implementation of this supposed consensus has still been<br />

lacking in practice, and by focusing on congestion rather than sustainability, the new EU<br />

White Paper on Transport even retreats from earlier, more ambitious policy approaches.<br />

So in the future, EU transport policy should not concentrate not so much on eliminating<br />

“missing links” and “bottlenecks” as on eliminating the predominance of the “missing<br />

link” and “bottleneck” rhetoric.<br />

10.4.4 Making the “Who Benefits” Question More Transparent<br />

Trade offs, particularly between local and international beneficiaries, need to be<br />

more clearly assessed. Even for an oversimplified case where one divides beneficiaries<br />

into only two main groups, namely international and local beneficiaries, there are still<br />

always at least four different argumentative scenarios describing possible outcomes.<br />

Using the M0 ring road as an example, table 10.1 illustrates the possibilities.


431<br />

Table 10.1 A Two-Dimensional “Who-Benefits?” - Matrix Based on the M0 Case<br />

International Actors<br />

Win<br />

Lose<br />

Local Actors<br />

Win<br />

Lose<br />

Scenario A<br />

- transit traffic effectively rerouted<br />

and<br />

- local access & efficiency improved<br />

Scenario C<br />

- transit traffic effectively rerouted<br />

but<br />

- impacts on local area negative<br />

Scenario B<br />

- no benefits for international traffic<br />

but<br />

- local access & efficiency improved<br />

Scenario D<br />

- no benefits for international traffic<br />

and<br />

- impacts on local area negative<br />

Of course, the reality is much more complicated, since different sections of the<br />

ring road have different functions and hence different main beneficiaries. Also, local<br />

actors would necessarily have to be further distinguished into inner city and suburban<br />

actors as well as into those actors primarily interested in economic growth and those<br />

interested in environmental sustainability. International actors might have to be further<br />

differentiated into the EU as a whole, (geo-political) specific member state interests,<br />

competitive economic interests and the interests of different EU populations. In the end,<br />

the ultimate “Who-benefits” question remains controversial and unresolved in most<br />

cases. Including costs and benefits at a wider geographical scale and making them<br />

transparent during the assessment stage would already do much to address this problem.<br />

10.4.5 Rethinking the Relationship between Traffic and Spatial Arguments<br />

Traffic arguments need to be clearly separated from spatial arguments but they<br />

cannot be assessed independently. At first glance, such a separation sounds contradictory<br />

to the recurring call for a better integration of transportation and land-use planning. In<br />

fact, the demand is highly supportive of this goal, in the sense that there can be no


432<br />

effective transport planning and policy making without adequate information and<br />

assessment on the specific expected land-use impacts of a planned transportation<br />

investment. Yet while many of the transport benefits are expected to be immediate<br />

benefits, effects from changes in the land use structure only accrue over the medium to<br />

long term. Moreover, direct and indirect effects need to be differentiated. Previous<br />

assessment procedures never captured these effects, but many sophisticated new models<br />

and methodologies have been developed under the EU’s 4 th and 5 th Framework programs<br />

that successfully include spatial, long-term, and indirect effects. Now the EU needs to<br />

ensure that these additional tools are further refined and finally applied in practice. 3<br />

10.4.6 Strengthen Local Planning and Land Use Regulations<br />

There is a clear need to significantly strengthen local planning and land use<br />

regulations in order to counteract the tendencies for sprawling land uses next to bypass<br />

exits and intersections. In particular, large-scale international road infrastructure<br />

investments in major urban regions should not be approved without a consistent regional<br />

development plan. The key problem with curbing ex-urban sprawl is that both inside and<br />

outside the EU, almost all regional development bodies lack the legal decision-making<br />

authority to successfully arbitrate between the incongruent development interest of major<br />

cities and their surrounding communities, let alone successfully protect suburban green<br />

3 Note that for the TENs, the SASI model is presently being updated under the EU’s 5 th Framework Project<br />

IASON (http://www.inro.tno.nl/iason/). The project “Socio-Economic and Spatial Impacts of Transport<br />

Infrastructure Investments and Transport System Improvements” (SASI)<br />

aimed at the development of a comprehensive and transferable methodology for forecasting the<br />

socioeconomic and spatial impacts of large transport investments in Europe, in particular of different<br />

scenarios of the development of the trans-European transport networks (TETN) planned by the<br />

European Commission. With respect to the cohesion objective of the European Union the model was to<br />

answer the question which regions of the European Union are likely to benefit from the TETN and<br />

which regions are likely to be disadvantaged.<br />

See http://irpud.raumplanung.uni-dortmund.de/irpud/pro/sasi/sasi.htm


433<br />

space. Transport loans are usually either made to the national government or, in the case<br />

of public transit, to the city. In sum, there is little opportunity in the setup of current<br />

funding mechanisms to adequately account for the likely detrimental impacts of key<br />

transport infrastructures at the agglomeration level. Clearly, this situation should be<br />

rectified, if possible under EU Commission leadership. Additionally, local planning and<br />

land use regulations need to be strengthened in order to counteract sprawling land uses<br />

next to bypass exits and intersections.<br />

10.5 Outlook: Suggestions for Further Research<br />

Given the interdisciplinary scope of this study, there are a host of possibilities for<br />

further research. Suggestions are likely to vary significantly depending on people’s<br />

disciplinary roots. Political scientists might want to further investigate the relationship<br />

between my developed “discursive frameworks” and other meso-level theoretical<br />

constructs (such as epistemic communities, advocacy coalitions, discourse coalitions,<br />

entrepreneurship), while urban geographers and regional economists might instead want<br />

to further scrutinize the transformation of Budapest into an international logistics hub.<br />

Meanwhile, enlargement specialists will be eager to study the further development and<br />

de-centralization of the ISPA pre-accession instrument and its subsequent transitioning<br />

into structural funding under member state status.<br />

To me personally, the most appealing avenue for future research at the moment<br />

would be a further refinement of the theory-building aspects of this study. Most<br />

importantly, I would consider further elaborating my typology of “discursive<br />

frameworks.” For example, does my differentiation into five different approaches for


434<br />

“sustainable” policy-making work as well for other arenas of decision-making as for<br />

transport (e.g. housing, urban policy, energy)? Which sub-elements in the five different<br />

frameworks are compatible with each other, which will always remain mutually<br />

exclusive? What does this mean for the prospects of integrating some or all of the<br />

discursive frameworks into a larger, unifying perspective? What about the differentiation<br />

between more process-oriented and more outcome oriented frameworks? How exactly<br />

does the concept of “reflexive” rationality challenge prevailing planning theoretical<br />

distinctions between “instrumental” and “communicative” rationalities, and how does this<br />

factor into each of the five frameworks? There is much room for additional debate over<br />

each of these questions and beyond. Closely related to this, a second key interest of mine<br />

would lie in an expansion of the concept of “spatial storylines” to other arenas of<br />

decision-making. Additionally, a closer comparison of the German planning concept of<br />

“Leitbilder” and the Anglophone concept of “storylines” would seem fruitful.<br />

Put in the most general terms, I believe that the discourse-oriented and<br />

increasingly interdisciplinary strand in planning and policy studies of which my own<br />

study is obviously a part will continue to provide crucial insights into the shifting<br />

decision-making rationalities of different institutions and individual stakeholders in<br />

modern capitalist democracies, and I hope that both my present and future research might<br />

make a useful partial contribution to the accumulation of knowledge in that arena.<br />

Don't let it end like this. Tell them I said something.<br />

Pancho Villa (1877-1923) Last words<br />

Go on, get out. Last words are for fools who haven't said enough.<br />

Karl Marx (1818-1883) Last words to his housekeeper


435<br />

APPENDICES,<br />

GLOSSARY,<br />

BIBLIOGRAPHY &<br />

CURRICULUM VITA<br />

Annex I: Overview of IFI Lending to Poland and Hungary until 2001...................... 436<br />

Annex II: List of Key Contacts................................................................................... 441<br />

Annex III: List of Relevant Conferences, Seminars & Writings ................................ 446<br />

Annotated Glossary of Terms, Acronyms and Abbreviations.................................... 449<br />

Bibliography ............................................................................................................... 455<br />

Curriculum Vita .......................................................................................................... 483


436<br />

Annex I: Overview of IFI Lending to Poland and Hungary until 2001 1<br />

Table A.1 EIB Transport Loans to Poland (1990-2001)*<br />

Size<br />

PROJECT<br />

Sector (Mio €)<br />

EIB 1994 - Rehabilitation of the highway Wroclaw - Opole; and construction of a Road 125<br />

new highway from Opole to Gliwice (part of TEN)<br />

EIB 1996 - TEN A-4 motorway: rehabilitation & upgrading of the 70 km road Road 100<br />

Wroclaw-Opole to motorway standard, 56 km of new motorway Opole-Gliwice<br />

EIB 1998 - Construction of 25 km section of A4 motorway south to Katowice Road 150<br />

EIB 1998 - Construction of urban expressway in Katowice area Road 100<br />

EIB 1998 - Construction of Poznan by-pass on A2 motorway Road 130<br />

EIB 2000 - Construction of motorway south-west of Gliwice, Upper Silesia<br />

Road<br />

46<br />

EIB 2000 - A2 motorway south of Poznan, Corridor II (<strong>Berlin</strong>-Warsaw link) Road 275<br />

EIB 2000 - Modernization of road section bypassing Gdynia, Sopot & Gdansk Road 33<br />

EIB 1993 - National Railways - Rehabilitation of Corridor II (<strong>Berlin</strong>-Warsaw line) Rail 200<br />

EIB 1995 - Loan to finance upgrading of a 37km section of the TEN E-20 Rail 40<br />

railway line <strong>Berlin</strong>-Warsaw-Minsk-Moscow (Corridor II)<br />

EIB 1990 - Polish Railway Society - Modernization of railway company's own Rail 20<br />

telecommunications network and locomotive repair centres<br />

EIB 1992 - Polish Transport Ministry - Modernization of Warsaw (Okecie) Air & 50<br />

airport<br />

Water<br />

EIB 1997 - Flood Damage Reconstruction - ECU 225 mio: rebuild roads, Other 300<br />

municipal infrastructure, flood protection infrastructure; ECU 75 mio. to railway<br />

company PKP: reconstruction of tracks, viaducts, electrical equipment<br />

EIB 1997 City of Katowice: improving urban infrastructure in Katowice: two road<br />

bypasses, a pumping station for the sewage system and a municipal landfill<br />

Other 20<br />

EIB 1998 - Construction of Krakow Fast Tram<br />

Public<br />

Transit<br />

* By 2002, additional road & rail loans were being considered to co-finance ISPA projects<br />

EIB Poland (€ 1634 million)<br />

Public Transit<br />

22%<br />

Air & Water<br />

3%<br />

Rail<br />

16%<br />

Road<br />

59%<br />

Source: Own Compilation using data from the EIB website and the CEE Bankwatch<br />

Network MDB Database<br />

45<br />

1 Only World Bank IBRD loans are included in the analysis. The International Bank for Reconstruction<br />

and Development (IBRD) is the regular lending arm of the World Bank. Note that the World Bank Group<br />

also has three other lending arms: the private sector IFC (International Finance Corporation), the IDA<br />

(International Development Association) and MIGA (Multilateral Gurarantee Association). IDA and MIGA<br />

do not apply to CEECs, and the role of the IFC in transport infrastructure provision is also negligible.<br />

There was, however, one IFC loan to Hungary to Malev Hungarian Airlines in 1998 in the amount of $80<br />

million to assist partial privatization.


437<br />

Table A.2 EIB Transport Loans to Hungary (1990-2001)*<br />

PROJECT<br />

EIB 1992 –Building of a bypass road near Sopron and Szolnok as well as<br />

rehabilitation measures<br />

EIB 1993 - Building and rehabilitation of parts of transit-roads and bypass<br />

road north of Budapest [i.e. the northern section of the M0 ring road]<br />

EIB 1996 - Extension of the M3 toll motorway from Budapest to the Ukrainian<br />

border<br />

EIB 1997 - Hungarian Railways - to improve efficiency, service and<br />

competitiveness of the Hungarian railways<br />

EIB 1998 - Hungarian railways - Upgrading of 340 km of rail track on four lines<br />

(part of the core network on the priority international corridors Dresden-<br />

Budapest-Bucharest/Sofia and Triest-Budapest-Lvov), in addition: equipment<br />

modernization<br />

Sector<br />

Size<br />

(Mio €)<br />

Road 50<br />

Road 72<br />

Road 95<br />

Rail 120<br />

Rail 60<br />

EIB 1992 - Ministry for Transport - Upgrading of air traffic control system Air & Water 20<br />

EIB 1998 - Construction of fourth metro line connecting South Buda and Pest<br />

EIB 1998 - Improvements to urban transport, sewerage, solid waste disposal<br />

and urban amenities in Budapest<br />

Public<br />

Transit<br />

Public<br />

Transit<br />

50<br />

50<br />

* By April 2002, the following loans were under appraisal to co-finance ISPA projects:<br />

EIB 2002 - Railways III (ISPA co-financing) for the rehabilitation and<br />

modernization of Corridor IV Budapest-Cegled-Szolnok-Lököshaza (Phase II)<br />

Rail 110<br />

EIB 2002 – Roads III (ISPA co-financing) for individual investment schemes<br />

with the aim to achieve 11.5 ton axle load bearing capacity<br />

EIB Hungary (€ 517 million)<br />

Road 60<br />

Public Transit<br />

19%<br />

Air & Water<br />

4%<br />

Road<br />

42%<br />

Rail<br />

35%<br />

Source: Own Compilation using data from the EIB website & the CEE Bankwatch MDB<br />

Database


438<br />

Table A.3 EBRD and IBRD Transport Loans to Poland (1990-2001)<br />

Size<br />

PROJECT<br />

Sector<br />

(Mio)<br />

EBRD 1993 - Motorway Development Project; complete motorway construction<br />

projects, introduce highway tolls, develop a strategy for national road network Roads € 45<br />

EBRD 1994 - Railway Modernization Polish state railways, assist with<br />

rehabilitation and modernization of corridor (<strong>Berlin</strong>)-Katowice-Warsaw Railway € 50<br />

EBRD 1997 - Europort Gdansk Grain Terminal Port € 29<br />

EBRD 1998 - City of Wroclaw - flood repair - purchase of equipment, civil<br />

works, related services for the rehabilitation of the city's tram tracks, cabling<br />

system, road repairs, the refurbishment of flooded bus and tram depots<br />

EBRD 1998 Krakow Urban Transport Project - to enable Poland's third largest<br />

city to finance a fast tram link running along its north-south axis. The long-term<br />

financing is based on a direct loan to the city with no sovereign guarantee<br />

EBRD 2000 - Warsaw Traffic Management Project: loan to the city for an<br />

urban traffic control system, including road improvements<br />

Public<br />

Transport<br />

€ 16<br />

Public<br />

Transport € 45<br />

Public<br />

Transport € 15<br />

Public<br />

Transport € 17<br />

EBRD 2000 - Gdansk and Sopot Urban Transport Project: finance urban<br />

transport infrastructure: tram systems, road underpasses, traffic management<br />

EBRD 2000 - PKP Restructuring and Privatization Project: improve the<br />

productivity and competitiveness of rail transport services by funding labor<br />

severance payments as part of restructuring. Railway € 100<br />

IBRD 1993 - Modernization and transformation of the transport sector by<br />

investing in the program of the General Directorate of Public Roads Roads $ 176<br />

IBRD 1997 - Port Access and Management - improvement of land and sea<br />

access to the ports of Gdansk, Gdynia, and Szczecin-Swinoujscie Roads $ 59<br />

IBRD 1998 - The road sector will be modernized and flood damaged roads and<br />

bridges will be repaired Roads € 268<br />

IBRD 2001 - Mitigate the social consequences of layoffs of some 37,000<br />

workers resulting from commercialization and partial privatization of the state<br />

railways, and prepare the transport system for entry into the European Union. Railway $ 101<br />

IBRD 2001 - This investment loan will help improve the Szczecin-Swinoujscie<br />

Seaway and support construction of new berths and cargo-handling areas<br />

within the existing port, resulting in reduction of cost and transit time, and<br />

benefiting the national community. Shipping $ 38.5<br />

EBRD Poland (€ 517.4 Million)<br />

Road<br />

9%<br />

Port<br />

6%<br />

IBRD Poland ($ 687 million)<br />

Shipping<br />

6%<br />

Rail<br />

29%<br />

Public<br />

Transit<br />

56%<br />

Rail<br />

16%<br />

Road<br />

78%<br />

Source: Own Compilation using World Bank and EBRD websites and the CEE<br />

Bankwatch MDB Database


439<br />

Table A.4 EBRD and IBRD Transport Loans in Hungary (1989-2001) 2<br />

PROJECT<br />

Sector<br />

EBRD 1993 - Budapest Public Transport Rehabilitation Project; for the<br />

rehabilitation of the city's public transport<br />

Public<br />

Transport € 64<br />

EBRD 1997 - MÁV railcar modernization and marketing project - to improve<br />

services and financial performance of railway services in Hungary Railway € 40<br />

EBRD 1998 - Hungarian railways - Refurbishment of 235 passenger coaches,<br />

the upgrading of up to 250 freight wagons in order to reduce operating and<br />

maintenance costs, improve quality of services, increase cost recovery Railway € 40<br />

EBRD 1999 - Budapest Intermodal Logistics Centre, Basic Infrastructure - to<br />

help finance private construction of a railway line connection servicing a new<br />

private logistics centre in Budapest Railway € 10<br />

EBRD 1992 - Budapest Orbital Motorway; Partial Financing of construction of<br />

part of the road network, and consultancy services Roads € 21<br />

Size<br />

(Mio)<br />

EBRD 1993 - M1-M15 Toll Motorways; Construction of 43 km motorway from<br />

Györ to the Austrian border and 15 km motorway towards Bratislava, to be run<br />

as toll roads Roads € 126<br />

EBRD 1995 - M5 Toll Motorway - first phase of a motorway to be built and<br />

operated by a private, special-purpose company Roads € 120<br />

EBRD 1999 - M1-M15 Motorway Restructured Project - to ensure the<br />

continued operation of the motorway Roads € 67<br />

IBRD 1989 - Inv. in rail, trucking, highways, urban transport General $ 95<br />

IBRD 1993 - Highway-rehabilitation, road-safety program Roads $ 90<br />

IBRD 1995 - Budapest Urban Transport - (a) replacement of 50 buses with<br />

low-polluting and energy-efficient substitutes; (b) rehabilitation of 47 km of<br />

worn out tramway tracks and purchase of track maintenance equipment; (c)<br />

automatic vehicle monitoring system<br />

Public<br />

Transport<br />

$ 38<br />

EBRD Hungary (€ 488 million)<br />

IBRD Hungary ($ 223 million)<br />

Road<br />

69%<br />

Public<br />

Transit<br />

13%<br />

Rail<br />

18%<br />

Public<br />

Transit<br />

17%<br />

Road<br />

40%<br />

General<br />

43%<br />

Source: Own Compilation using World Bank and EBRD websites and the CEE<br />

Bankwatch MDB Database<br />

2 Additionally, there was already a World Bank IBRD loan in the amount of $75 to Hungary in 1985 (Loan<br />

Nr. 2557-HU). Besides funding the southern section of the M0, this loan also provided assistance to the<br />

Hungarian State Railways (MÁV) and the trucking company Hungarocamion.


440<br />

Figure A.1 TINA Needs 2000-2015 vs. IFI TINA Network Loans 1990-2000 3<br />

TINA Needs Poland 2000-2015<br />

(€36.42 billion)<br />

Air & Sea<br />

11%<br />

Rail<br />

40%<br />

Terminals<br />

0%<br />

Road<br />

49%<br />

IFI Loans TINA Network Poland 1990-2000<br />

(€ 2.79 billion)<br />

Rail<br />

24%<br />

Air & Sea<br />

6%<br />

Road<br />

70%<br />

TINA Needs Hungary 2000-2015<br />

(€10.16 billion)<br />

Air & Sea<br />

8%<br />

Rail<br />

40%<br />

Terminals<br />

7%<br />

Road<br />

45%<br />

IFI Loans TINA Network Hungary 1990-2000<br />

(€1.13 billion)<br />

Air & Sea<br />

Rail<br />

2%<br />

29%<br />

Road<br />

69%<br />

Source: Own compilation using data from the CEE Bankwatch Network, the World<br />

Bank, the EBRD, the EIB, and the TINA Final Report<br />

3 The calculation of total international funds for TINA networks excluded all IFI loans for public transit,<br />

since these are not relevant for TINA. Also, World Bank funds are somewhat underestimated in the<br />

calculated totals, since IBRD credits disbursed in US$ were translated into € at a simple 1$=1€ exchange<br />

rate. Since most IBRD funds were road or public transit funds, this means that the actual balance is even<br />

more strongly biased in favor of road infrastructures.


441<br />

Annex II: List of Key Contacts 4<br />

ACAD University – Academic / Consultant CEC European Commission<br />

IO International Organization (e.g. OECD/ECMT, UN) GOV National Government<br />

For additional abbreviations (DG, IFI, ISPA, HU, PL, SEA, TEN, TINA etc.) please assume the obvious or consult the glossary.<br />

Org. Name Last Name Position Key Area of Expertise Remarks<br />

ACAD Andrzej Brzezinski Warsaw University of<br />

Technology<br />

Polish transport policy Meeting in Warsaw, July 2000<br />

& at FIST Workshop, Jan. 2001<br />

ACAD Eva Ehrlich Economics Professor, Institute<br />

for World Economics, Hungary<br />

Transport modernization,<br />

Hungarian transport policy<br />

Interview in Budapest, August<br />

2000<br />

ACAD Tamas Fleischer Economist, Hungarian Institute<br />

for World Economics<br />

Hungarian transport policy Interview in Budapest, August<br />

2000<br />

ACAD Liana Giorgi Researcher, ICCR Vienna TEN-CODE & TENASSESS<br />

research projects<br />

Meeting during Trans-Talk<br />

Workshop, November 2000<br />

ACAD Wolfgang Hager Centre for European Policy<br />

Studies<br />

EU transport policy,<br />

especially rail restructuring<br />

Interview in Brussels, June<br />

2000<br />

ACAD Janos Monigl Transman Ltd Consulting Hungarian transport policy,<br />

especially rail<br />

Meetings OECD Paris ,June<br />

2000 & in Budapest, Jan. 2001<br />

ACAD Rana Roy Consultant TENs, especially rail policy,<br />

(Worked for ECIS)<br />

Meeting during Trans-Talk<br />

Workshop, November 2000<br />

ACAD Wojciech Suchorzewski Warsaw University of<br />

Technology<br />

EU & CEE Transport policy,<br />

especially Poland<br />

Multiple meetings / talks in<br />

Warsaw etc, last July 2000.<br />

ACAD Katalin Tanczos Head of Transport Economics<br />

Dept., Tech. Univ. Budapest<br />

Transport modernization<br />

Hungarian transport policy<br />

OECD seminar, June 2000 &<br />

Interview Budapest, July 2000,<br />

CEC Detlev Boeing International Relations, DG<br />

Transport / DG Enlargement<br />

CEE Accession, Transport<br />

Acquis<br />

Several meetings as part of<br />

Helcom study<br />

4 Note that contacts made during the many European transport-related workshops & seminars which I attended during the research stage of the study (see Annex<br />

III) are only listed here if the ensuing talks during those meetings yielded particular insights and/or supplied new, previously unavailable information.


442<br />

CEC Ulrike Braun Task Force Accession<br />

Negotiations<br />

Transport Acquis Interview in Brussels with M.<br />

Garcia Fidalgo, June 2000<br />

CEC Douglas Carpenter Administrator Infrastructure<br />

Projects, DG Transport<br />

TEN policy<br />

Two interviews in Brussels,<br />

2000. (Now in different DG)<br />

CEC Lewis Dijkstra DG Regional Policy EU Urban Policy Meeting in Brussels, May 2001<br />

(Rutgers PhD cand. until 2000)<br />

CEC Christos Dionelis TINA Vienna,, then DG<br />

Transport<br />

TINA (Wrote the final report) Interview in Brussels, June<br />

2000.<br />

CEC Jean Dropinski DG Regional Policy, Principal<br />

administrator, ISPA<br />

ISPA (esp. Poland)<br />

Interview in Brussels, June<br />

2000.<br />

CEC Marta Garcia-<br />

Fidalgo<br />

Task Force Accession<br />

Negotiations<br />

Transport Acquis<br />

Interview in Brussels together<br />

with Ulrike Braun, June 2000<br />

CEC Stephen Garland Detached National Expert, DG<br />

Transport<br />

Responsible for SEA manual Short meeting in Brussels,<br />

2000. Now back in UK<br />

CEC Winfried Grüter DG Transport TENs & TINA Interview in Brussels, June<br />

2000<br />

CEC Fernando Hervas<br />

Soriano<br />

Administrator, DG<br />

Environment<br />

ISPA cooperation<br />

One interview, one meeting in<br />

Brussels<br />

CEC Klaus Keisel Detached National Expert, DG<br />

Environment<br />

Integration of environmental<br />

concerns into transport policy<br />

Interview in Brussels, May<br />

2001<br />

CEC Stephane Khelif Detached National Expert, DG<br />

Transport<br />

TINA, TENs, Balkan<br />

reconstruction<br />

Two interviews in Brussels, last<br />

June 2000.<br />

CEC Anders Lundström Railway Expert, DG Transport Railway policy Interview in Brussels as part of<br />

Helcom Study, 1999<br />

CEC Angela Martinez-<br />

Sarasola<br />

DG Regional Policy<br />

ISPA and accession<br />

preparation Hungary<br />

Interview in Brussels, June<br />

2000.<br />

CEC Daniel Mouque DG Regional Policy Cohesion and Transport Interview in Brussels, May<br />

2001<br />

CEC Sian Prout Administrator, DG Transport International Relations Provided key TINA/TEN<br />

materials


443<br />

CEC Tom Robbert SCR, EU lending to nonmembers<br />

Phare, external EU support Interview in Brussels, June<br />

2000 (SCR Unit now dissolved)<br />

CEC Jonathan Scheele Ex-DG TREN (Now Head of<br />

EU Delegation in Romania)<br />

Helsinki Corridors, Pan-Eur.<br />

Ministers Meetings 93-97<br />

Interview in Brussels, June<br />

2000<br />

CEC Brendan Smyth DG Regional Policy ISPA, long CEEC experience<br />

as PHARE adviser<br />

Interview in Brussels, June<br />

2000.<br />

CEC David Sweet DG Regional Policy ISPA Trans-Talk conference, Nov.<br />

2000; Lunch, May 2001<br />

EU-<br />

CEE<br />

Axel Badrichani EU Delegation to Hungary Transport concessions Interview in Budapest, July<br />

2000<br />

EU-<br />

CEE<br />

Hana Martinovska Program Director, Phare Multicountry<br />

Transport Program<br />

Phare multi-country transport<br />

program<br />

Interview in Prague, 2000 (just<br />

before the unit was dissolved)<br />

GOV- Axel Friedrich Head, Transport Policy Section, Sustainable Transport Policy, Multiple meetings (during<br />

GER<br />

German Environmental Agency regulatory aspects, emissions Helcom, FIST, UN CSD etc.)<br />

GOV-<br />

HU<br />

Laszlo Becker General Director, Int. Funding<br />

HU Environment Ministry<br />

ISPA (esp. Environment) Interview in Budapest, August<br />

2000<br />

GOV-<br />

HU<br />

Gyözö Kenez International funding, Ministry<br />

of Transport<br />

ISPA Hungary<br />

Interview / Meeting in<br />

Budapest, August 2000<br />

GOV-<br />

HU<br />

Katalin Pallai Budapest City Municipality,<br />

Assistant to the Mayor<br />

Budapest strategic urban<br />

development / urban planning<br />

Meetings Salzburg Seminar,<br />

June 2000; Budapest, Jan. 2001<br />

GOV-<br />

HU<br />

Jozsef Uszta Hungarian Regional<br />

Environment Ministry<br />

Phare regional environment Interview in Budapest, August<br />

2000<br />

GOV- Jan Friedberg Undersecretary of State, Polish Polish transport policy, Polish Interview in Warsaw, July 2000<br />

PL<br />

Transport Ministry<br />

ISPA strategy<br />

& prev. contact via NGO work<br />

GOV- Malgorzata<br />

Mokranzka Section Head, EU Integration, Polish road transport, EU Interview in Warsaw, July 2000<br />

PL<br />

Public Roads Directorate integration / int. cooperation<br />

GOV- Jaroslaw Waskiewicz Division Chief, Finance Polish transport policy, EU & Interview in Warsaw with<br />

PL<br />

Department, Transport Ministry IFI loans to Poland<br />

Stanislaw Zielinski, July 2000<br />

GOV- Stanislaw Zielinski Deputy Director, Finance Polish transport policy, EU & Interview in Warsaw with J.<br />

PL<br />

Department, Transport Ministry IFI loans to Poland<br />

Waskiewicz, July 2000


444<br />

IFI Peter Carter Environmental Coordinator,<br />

Projects Directorate, EIB<br />

EIB environmental policy,<br />

relation to transport policy<br />

Meeting / email contacts as part<br />

of Helcom study 1998-1999<br />

IFI Philip Cornwell Deputy Director, Transport<br />

Team, EBRD<br />

Transport policy<br />

& appraisal<br />

Meeting / informal talk, FIST<br />

Vienna, January 2001<br />

IFI Bill Kennedy Senior Environmental Adviser,<br />

EBRD<br />

Environmental Appraisal Repeated talks & meetings<br />

1998-1999 as part of Helcom<br />

IFI Slobodan Mitric Senior Urban Transport Staff,<br />

World Bank<br />

International Transport<br />

Policy, CEE and beyond<br />

Repeated talks & meetings<br />

1995-, last in Vienna, Jan. 2001<br />

IFI Eva Molnar Transport Sector Manager,<br />

ECA Region, World Bank<br />

Transport Infrastructure in<br />

Central Eastern Europe<br />

Interview in Washington,<br />

February 2000<br />

IO Ann Dom Project Manager, Transport and<br />

Environment, EEA<br />

SEA, transport and<br />

environment<br />

Several meetings 1998-1999, as<br />

part of Helcom study<br />

IO Jack Short OECD/ECMT Secretary<br />

General<br />

OECD Sprawl Seminar, Paris,<br />

June 2000, additional lunch talk<br />

IO Peter Wiederkehr OECD environment directorate Environment and Transport,<br />

OECD EST study<br />

Repeated meetings (Helcom,<br />

FIST Vienna), last Jan. 2001<br />

NGO Paul Beeckmans Community of European<br />

Railways<br />

Railway policy<br />

Interview in Brussels, June<br />

2000.<br />

NGO Jiri Dusik Regional Environmental Center<br />

for Central Eastern Europe<br />

Environmental Scoping of<br />

TINA corridor, SEA<br />

Interview / Talk in Budapest,<br />

August 2000 & FIST, Jan. 2001<br />

NGO Frazer Goodwin Policy Officer, European Fed. EU Sustainable Transport Multiple meetings in Brussels<br />

for Transport & Environment Policy<br />

NGO Joszef Feiler CEE Bankwatch, Hungary IFIs, Hungarian transport<br />

policy<br />

Interview / talk in Budapest,<br />

August 2000<br />

NGO Ferec Joo Hungarian Traffic Club and<br />

T&E Board Member<br />

Hungarian and CEE<br />

Transport policy, esp. Rail<br />

Multiple meetings in Budapest<br />

and elsewhere, 1995-2001<br />

NGO Andras Lukas Clean Air Action Group,<br />

Hungary<br />

Hungarian environmental and<br />

transport policy, urban sprawl<br />

Multiple meetings in Budapest<br />

and elsewhere, 1995-2001<br />

NGO Pavel Pribyl National coordinator, CEE<br />

Bankwatch Czech Republic<br />

IFIs in CEE Meeting in Prague, June 2000.


445<br />

NGO Hana Rihkovsky Comm. of European Railways, European Rail Policy Meeting in Brussels, July 2000<br />

Ex-Belgian Transport Ministry<br />

NGO Frank van Schaik ASEED transport coordinator NGO Anti-TEN transport<br />

activism, MATE map<br />

Meeting in Amsterdam, July<br />

2000<br />

NGO Beatrice Schell Director, European Federation<br />

for Transport & Environment<br />

EU Sustainable Transport<br />

Policy<br />

Multiple Meetings in Brussels<br />

and elsewhere<br />

NGO Magda Stoczkiewicz CEE Bankwatch Network, EU<br />

Coordinator, c/o FOE Europe<br />

Environmental Advocacy Multiple talks in Brussels,<br />

Amsterdam & CEE 1995-<br />

NGO Janos Zlinsky Regional Environmental Center<br />

for Central Eastern Europe<br />

General environmental policy<br />

in CEE<br />

Interview / Talk in Budapest,<br />

August 2000


446<br />

Annex III: List of Relevant Conferences, Seminars & Writings<br />

I. Relevant academic conferences/seminars attended during the research period:<br />

“Planning and Policy-Making in the EU: A Typology of Five Different Discursive<br />

Frameworks for Decision-Making.” and “Sustainable Mobility – An Elusive Concept?<br />

Interpreting EU Transport Policy as a (failed?) Example of Ecological Modernization”<br />

Papers presented at the XVI AESOP Congress, Volos, July 10-15, 2002<br />

“The future of sustainable development in the European Union: An analysis of four<br />

different storylines.“ Paper presented at the Urban Affairs Association Annual Meeting,<br />

March 20-23, 2002, Boston<br />

“Bourgeois Utopias Budapest-Style Or: The Rise (and Fall?) of Suburbia in Central<br />

Europe Paper presented at the Young Housing Researchers Workshop in Warsaw, June<br />

22-24, 2001 and presented at the ACSP conference, Cleveland, Ohio, 6-11 November<br />

2001<br />

“Does Brussels help finance urban sprawl in Budapest? EU Infrastructure support seen<br />

from a critical local perspective.” World Planning Schools Congress, Shanghai, China,<br />

11-16 July 2001.<br />

“Transport investments and regional development: Myths and realities in the New<br />

Europe.” ACSP conference in Atlanta, Georgia, November 2-5, 2000<br />

“Center-Periphery Dynamics in the New Europe and Their Impact on Transport<br />

Infrastructure Planning in the Baltic Sea Region.” International Planning History<br />

Conference, Helsinki, Finland, August 20-23, 2000 (available under<br />

http://www.itdp.org/pub.html)<br />

“The EU’s Role in Transport Infrastructure Development in Central & Eastern Europe in<br />

the Context of Enlargement,” AESOP Congress, Brno, Czech Republic, July 18-22, 2000<br />

Pre-Conference AESOP PhD Workshop, Brno, Czech Republic, July 14-17, 2000<br />

(Recipient of Fannie Mae/ACSP dissertation travel grant)<br />

”Trans-European Network Expansion and Sustainable Regional Development: The Via<br />

Baltica Example.” XIII AESOP Congress, Bergen, Norway, July 7-11, 1999<br />

Pre-Conference AESOP PhD Workshop, Finse, Norway, July 3-6, 1999<br />

“Review of Transport Infrastructure Decision-Making in Helcom PITF Member<br />

Countries: Case Studies of Latvia and Poland.” Second Helcom PITF Workshop on<br />

Transport, Swedish Environmental Protection Agency, Stockholm, March 3-5 1999.


447<br />

”Poverty Alleviation through Sustainable Transport Development? Recent Initiatives at<br />

the World Bank.” ACSP Conference, November 4-8 1998, Pasadena, California.<br />

The Use of Policy Analysis in the European Union. NYU Robert F. Wagner School of<br />

Public Service, European Summer Institute in Lyon, France & Brussels, Belgium.<br />

Participant in a 3 week summer seminar, June/July 1998<br />

“NGO's Institutional Role in Advancing Sustainable Transport Development.” Transport<br />

Working Group, UNCHS International Conference on Governance and Participation,<br />

Urban Poverty Forum, Florence, Italy, 9-13 November, 1997<br />

II. Relevant professional conferences/meetings attended during the research period<br />

United Nations Commission on Sustainable Development, Ninth Session (CSD 9), New<br />

York, April 16-27, 2001. Member of the National Delegation of Germany (NGO<br />

Transport Expert).<br />

World Bank Institute / LGI Urban Management Course, Open Society, Budapest,<br />

Hungary, Nov. 26 – Dec. 1, 2000 and Jan. 22 –27, 2001. Participant in a training course<br />

for urban professionals in CEE.<br />

Financing Sustainable Transport Infrastructure and Technology: CEEC and NIS (FIST<br />

Workshop), International workshop organized by the Austrian Energy Agency<br />

(Energieverwertungsagentur – EVA) on behalf of the United Nations Department of<br />

Economic and Social Affairs (UNDESA), the Central European Initiative (CEI), and the<br />

Austrian Transport and Environment Ministries, Vienna, January 25-26, 2001 (also see<br />

http://www.eva.wsr.ac.at/(en)/service/veranst/fist.htm)<br />

International conference on EIB policies and projects in Europe from an environmental,<br />

access to information and public participation perspective, Hosted by GUE/NGL (the<br />

confederal group of the European United Left/Nordic Green Left), Brussels, European<br />

Parliament, November 9-10, 2000<br />

2 nd Trans-Talk Expert Workshop for the Thematic Network “Policy and Project<br />

Evaluation Methodologies,” organized by the Interdisciplinary Center for Comparative<br />

Research in the Social Sciences (ICCR) and the EU Directorate General Transport &<br />

Energy, Brussels, November 6-8, 2000. (Presentation on “Old Myths and New Realities<br />

of Transport Assessment: Implications for EU interventions in Central Europe.” Edited<br />

contributions to be published in book format in late 2002.)<br />

Symposium on Intelligent Mobility in Urban Regions, Urban 21 Global Conference on<br />

the Urban Future, <strong>Berlin</strong>, July 4-6, 2000


448<br />

Evaluation Methodologies for Infrastructure Investments and Urban Sprawl: Invited<br />

Expert Seminar, European Conference of Ministers of Transport/OECD, Paris, June 29-<br />

30, 2000<br />

Environmentally Sustainable Transportation Investment Decision-Making in the Baltic<br />

Sea Region: Proposals and Recommendations. Workshop organized for the Helsinki<br />

Commission at the European Commission, Directorate General for Transport, Brussels,<br />

March 2, 2000<br />

III. Additional writings related to the dissertation topic<br />

“Cohesion, Polycentricity, Missing Links and Bottlenecks: Conflicting Spatial Storylines<br />

for Pan-European Transport Investments” European Planning Studies (forthcoming in<br />

the February/March 2003 issue).<br />

“A Sustainable Transport Convention for the New Europe.” In: Dodds, Felix (ed.). 2000.<br />

Earth Summit 2002 – A New Deal. London: Earthscan, pp. 109-123.<br />

Major Transportation Infrastructure Investment Decision-Making, and Its Impact on the<br />

Long-Term Sustainability of the Baltic Sea. Helcom PITF Project #298 25 161. Written<br />

with Walter Hook, with contributions from W. Suchorzewsky, and M. Stoczkeiwicz.<br />

<strong>Berlin</strong>: Umweltbundesamt, April 1999


449<br />

Annotated Glossary of Terms, Acronyms and Abbreviations<br />

€ Euro, European unitary currency since January 1 st , 2002<br />

acquis<br />

communautaire<br />

“The Community acquis or Community patrimony is the body of<br />

common rights and obligations which bind all the Member States<br />

together within the European Union. It is constantly evolving and …<br />

comprises not only Community law in the strict sense, but also all acts<br />

adopted under the second and third pillars of the European Union and,<br />

above all, the common objectives laid down in the Treaties. Applicant<br />

countries have to accept the Community acquis before they can join<br />

the European Union. Exemptions and derogations from the acquis are<br />

granted only in exceptional circumstances and are limited in scope.”<br />

EU Glossary<br />

CAAG<br />

CEC<br />

CEE<br />

CEE Bankwatch<br />

Network<br />

CEEC<br />

CEPS<br />

Committee of the<br />

Regions<br />

Clean Air Action Group, an environmental NGO in Hungary.<br />

http://www.levego.hu/angol.htm<br />

Commission of the European Communities, see “Commission”<br />

Central Eastern Europe<br />

A Central European watchdog NGO set up in 1995 monitoring IFI<br />

activities in the region. http://www.bankwatch.org/<br />

Central Eastern European Countries<br />

An EU policy think tank. Founded in 1983, the Centre for European<br />

Policy Studies is “dedicated to producing sound policy research<br />

leading to constructive solutions to the challenges facing Europe<br />

today.” http://www.ceps.be/<br />

Set up by the Maastricht Treaty. It consists of 222 representatives of<br />

local and regional authorities appointed by the Council for four years<br />

on the basis of proposals from the Member States. It is consulted by<br />

the Council or the Commission in areas affecting local and regional<br />

interests, including social and economic cohesion, the environment,<br />

and transport. The CoR may also issue opinions on its own initiative.<br />

http://www.cor.eu.int/<br />

Community acquis See “acquis communautaire”<br />

CSD<br />

a) Commission on Sustainable Development, the United Nations<br />

Commission responsible for implementing the Rio Earth Summit<br />

Agenda 21. http://www.un.org/esa/sustdev/


450<br />

CSD<br />

CTP<br />

DG<br />

b) Committee on Spatial Development, the EU Committee responsible<br />

for dealing with the “ESDP”<br />

Common Transport Policy “The aim of the common transport policy is<br />

to lay down common rules applicable to international transport to or<br />

from the territory of the Member States or passing across the territory<br />

of one or more of them (Articles 70 to 80 of the EC Treaty).” EU<br />

Glossary<br />

Directorate General<br />

DG Enlargement EU Commission Directorate General for Enlargement<br />

http://europa.eu.int/comm/enlargement/<br />

DG Regio EU Commission Directorate General for Regional Policy<br />

http://europa.eu.int/comm/regional_policy/index_en.htm<br />

DG TREN Directorate General for Transport and Energy, merged in 2000<br />

http://europa.eu.int/comm/dgs/energy_transport/index_en.html<br />

EAP<br />

EBRD<br />

ECMT<br />

ECU<br />

EEA<br />

EIB<br />

EMU<br />

ERT<br />

Environmental Action Program<br />

European Bank for Reconstruction and Development.<br />

http://www.ebrd.com<br />

The European Conference of Ministers of Transport (ECMT) is an<br />

intergovernmental organization established by a Protocol signed in<br />

Brussels on 17 October 1953. It provides European forum for policy<br />

cooperation at the ministerial level.<br />

http://www1.oecd.org/cem/about.htm<br />

European Currency Unit, the old, virtual European unitary currency<br />

unit before the Euro, 1 ECU = 1 €<br />

European Environment Agency http://www.eea.eu.int/<br />

European Investment Bank. Created in 1958 under the Treaty of<br />

Rome, the European Investment Bank is the financing institution of<br />

the European Union. Its task it “to contribute towards the integration,<br />

balanced development and economic and social cohesion of the<br />

Member Countries. To this end, it raises on the markets substantial<br />

volumes of funds which it directs on the most favourable terms<br />

towards financing capital projects according with the objectives of the<br />

Union. Outside the Union the EIB implements the financial<br />

components of agreements concluded under European development<br />

aid and cooperation policies.” http://www.eib.org<br />

Economic and Monetary Union. “Economic and monetary union<br />

(EMU) is the process whereby the economic and monetary policies of<br />

the Member States of the Union are being harmonised with a view to<br />

the introduction of a single currency.” EU Glossary<br />

European Round Table of Industrialists. Created in 1983, the ERT is<br />

“a forum of 42 European industrial leaders aiming at promoting the


451<br />

competitiveness and growth of Europe's economy.” See<br />

http://www.ert.be/<br />

ESDP European Spatial Development Perspective. http://europa.eu.<br />

int/comm/regional_policy/sources/docoffic/official/space_en.htm<br />

EU Commission “The European Commission is a body with powers of initiative,<br />

implementation, management and control. It is the guardian of the<br />

Treaties and the embodiment of the interests of the Community. It is<br />

composed of twenty independent members (two each from France,<br />

Germany, Italy, Spain and the United Kingdom and one each from all<br />

the other countries), including a President and two Vice-Presidents. It<br />

is appointed for a five-year term, by agreement among the Member<br />

States, and is subject to a vote of appointment by the European<br />

Parliament, to which it is answerable, before it can be sworn in. The<br />

Commissioners are assisted by an administration made up of<br />

directorates-general and specialised departments whose staff are<br />

divided mainly between Brussels and Luxembourg.” EU Glossary<br />

http://europa.eu.int/comm/<br />

EU Council<br />

EU Parliament<br />

Green Paper<br />

“The European Council is the term used to describe the regular<br />

meetings of the Heads of State or Government of the European Union<br />

Member States. … Its existence was given legal recognition by the<br />

Single European Act, while official status was conferred on it by the<br />

Treaty on European Union. It meets at least twice a year and the<br />

President of the European Commission attends as a full member. Its<br />

objectives are to give the European Union the impetus it needs in order<br />

to develop further and to define general policy guidelines.”<br />

EU Glossary http://ue.eu.int/<br />

“The European Parliament is the assembly of the representatives of the<br />

370 million Union citizens. … It considers the Commission's<br />

proposals and is associated with the Council in the legislative process,<br />

in some cases as co-legislator, by means of various procedures<br />

(codecision procedure, cooperation procedure, assent, advisory<br />

opinion etc.); it has the power of control over the Union's activities<br />

through its confirmation of the appointment of the Commission (and<br />

the right to censure it) and through the written and oral questions it can<br />

put to the Commission and the Council; it shares budgetary powers<br />

with the Council in voting on the annual budget, rendering it<br />

enforceable through the President of Parliament's signature, and<br />

overseeing its implementation. It also appoints an Ombudsman<br />

empowered to receive complaints from Union citizens concerning<br />

maladministration in the activities of the Community institutions or<br />

bodies.” EU Glossary http://www.europarl.eu.int/<br />

“Commission Green papers are documents intended to stimulate<br />

debate and launch a process of consultation at European level on a<br />

particular topic. These consultations may then lead to the publication


452<br />

of a White Paper, translating the conclusions of the debate into<br />

practical proposals for Community action.” EU Glossary<br />

Helsinki Corridors The ten multi-modal priority transport corridors agreed as at the Pan-<br />

European Transport Ministers Conference in 1997.<br />

HUF<br />

IBRD<br />

IFI<br />

ISPA<br />

KÖVIM<br />

LISF<br />

NGO<br />

M0<br />

Hungarian Forint, national currency<br />

The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development “aims to<br />

reduce poverty in middle-income and creditworthy poorer countries by<br />

promoting sustainable development, through loans, guarantees, and<br />

nonlending -including analytical and advisory-services.” Part of the<br />

“World Bank” Group<br />

International Financial Institution (e.g. World Bank, EIB, EBRD)<br />

Instrument for Structural Pre-Accession ISPA is the EU program<br />

providing pre-accession grants to the CEE candidate countries in the<br />

areas of transport and environment.<br />

http://europa.eu.int/comm/regional_policy/funds/ispa/ispa_en.htm<br />

Hungarian abbreviation for the former Hungarian Transport Ministry,<br />

now restructured as the Ministry of Economy and Transport.<br />

http://www.gm.hu/<br />

Large-Scale Infrastructure Facility, a PHARE-funded pre-cursor to<br />

ISPA. From 1998-99, the LISF was intended to cover the transition<br />

from PHARE to ISPA by funding select large-scale infrastructure<br />

projects in the candidate states, with an emphasis on co-financing with<br />

the IFIs.<br />

Non-governmental organization. Usually used to label environmental<br />

or civic organizations.<br />

(Planned) ring road around the Hungarian capital of Budapest<br />

Maastricht Treaty Treaty of the European Union (1992) a.k.a. TEU<br />

Ombudsman<br />

OECD<br />

“The European Ombudsman is appointed by the European Parliament<br />

after each election for the duration of Parliament's term of office. He is<br />

empowered to receive complaints from any citizen of the Union or any<br />

natural or legal person residing in a Member State concerning<br />

instances of maladministration in the activities of the Community<br />

institutions or bodies…. Where the Ombudsman establishes an<br />

instance of maladministration he refers the matter to the institution<br />

concerned, conducts an investigation, seeks a solution to redress the<br />

problem and, if necessary, submits draft recommendations to which<br />

the institution is required to reply in the form of a detailed report<br />

within three months.” EU Glossary<br />

The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Also<br />

see http://www.oecd.org


453<br />

Pan-European<br />

Corridors<br />

See “Helsinki Corridors”<br />

PHARE PHARE is a key source of EU grant funding for CEECs. The<br />

(francophone) acronym PHARE meant “Poland and Hungary -<br />

Assistance for Economic Reconstruction.” The acronym became<br />

common usage and was kept even after the program was extended to<br />

include other CEECs.<br />

http://europa.eu.int/comm/enlargement/pas/phare/<br />

SAPARD<br />

Pre-accession instrument for agricultural and rural development aid to<br />

the candidate countries http://europa.eu.int/comm/agriculture/<br />

external/enlarge/back/index_en.htm<br />

SDS Sustainable Development Strategy of the EU, published in 2001.<br />

http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/eussd/<br />

Subsidarity<br />

“The subsidiarity principle is intended to ensure that decisions are<br />

taken as closely as possible to the citizen and that constant checks are<br />

made as to whether action at Community level is justified in the light<br />

of the possibilities available at national, regional or local level.<br />

Specifically, it is the principle whereby the Union does not take action<br />

(except in the areas which fall within its exclusive competence) unless<br />

it is more effective than action taken at national, regional or local<br />

level. It is closely bound up with the principles of proportionality and<br />

necessity, which require that any action by the Union should not go<br />

beyond what is necessary to achieve the objectives of the Treaty.”<br />

EU Glossary<br />

TENs Trans-European Networks. Usually the generic term for<br />

interconnected networks and services available on a pan-European<br />

basis, in this study, “TENs” is frequently used as a short-hand for the<br />

EU’s Trans-European Transport Networks (TEN-T).<br />

http://www.europarl.eu.int/factsheets/4_6_1_en.htm<br />

TEU<br />

TINA<br />

ToA<br />

Treaty of the European Union (1992) a.k.a. Maastricht Treaty<br />

Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment for the CEE candidate<br />

countries. The TINA exercise was completed in 1999.<br />

“The Treaty of Amsterdam was adopted at the Amsterdam European<br />

Council on 16 and 17 June 1997 and signed on 2 October 1997 by the<br />

Foreign Ministers of the fifteen Member States. It entered into force<br />

on 1 May 1999 after ratification by all the Member States in<br />

accordance with their respective constitutional requirements. From<br />

the legal point of view, the Treaty amends certain provisions of the EU<br />

Treaty, the Treaties establishing the European Communities and<br />

certain related acts. It does not replace the other Treaties; rather, it<br />

stands alongside them.” EU Glossary


454<br />

T&E<br />

European Federation for Transport and Environment. The European<br />

umbrella organization for NGOs working in the field of transport and<br />

the environment. http://www.t-e.nu<br />

UN-ECE United Nations Economic Commission for Europe. Set up in 1947,<br />

UNECE has 55 member states. UNECE is one of five regional<br />

commissions of the United Nations and its activities include policy<br />

analysis, development of conventions, regulations and standards, and<br />

technical assistance. http://www.unece.org/<br />

White Paper<br />

World Bank<br />

WSSD<br />

Zl<br />

“Documents containing proposals for Community action in a specific<br />

area. In some cases they follow a Green Paper published to launch a<br />

consultation process at European level. Examples include the White<br />

Papers on the completion of the internal market, on growth,<br />

competitiveness and employment and the approximation of the laws of<br />

the associated states of Central and Eastern Europe in areas of<br />

relevance to the internal market. When a White Paper has been<br />

favourably received by the Council, it can become the action<br />

programme for the Union in the area concerned.” EU Glossary<br />

One of the world’s largest sources of development assistance, the<br />

World Bank “works in more than 100 developing economies with the<br />

primary focus of helping the poorest people and the poorest<br />

countries.” http://www.worldbank.org<br />

UN World Summit on Sustainable Development. The WSSD took<br />

place in Johannesburg, South Africa, from August 26 to September 4,<br />

2002. http://www.johannesburgsummit.org<br />

Polish Zloty, national currency


455<br />

Bibliography<br />

Aglietta, M. (1979). A Theory of Capitalist Regulation: The U.S. Experience. London, Verso.<br />

Albrechts, L. (2001). “How to Proceed from Image and Discourse to Action: As Applied to the<br />

Flemish Diamond.” Urban Studies 38(4): 733-745.<br />

Alexander, E. (2000). “Rationality Revisited: Planning Paradigms in a Post-postmodernist<br />

Perspective.” Journal of Planning Education and Research 19: 242-256.<br />

Allen, D. (2000). Cohesion and the Structural Funds. Policy-making in the European Union. H.<br />

Wallace and W. Wallace. Oxford; New York, Oxford University Press: 243-265.<br />

Allmendinger, P. (2001). Planning in Postmodern Times. London, Routledge.<br />

—— (2002a). Planning Theory. New York, Palgrave.<br />

—— (2002b). “Towards a Post-Positivist Typology of Planning Theory.” Planning Theory 1(1):<br />

77-99.<br />

Altvater, E. (1998). “Theoretical deliberation on time and space in post-socialist transformation.”<br />

Regional Studies 32(7): 591-605.<br />

Amin, A. (1994). Post-Fordism: A reader. Oxford, Blackwell.<br />

Amin, A. and J. Tomaney (1995). Behind the myth of European union: prospects for cohesion.<br />

London; New York, Routledge.<br />

Amin, A. and N. Thrift, Eds. (1995). Globalization, Institutions, and Regional Development in<br />

Europe. New York, Oxford University Press.<br />

Anand, S. and A. Sen (1994). Sustainable Human Development: Concepts and Priorities.<br />

Occasional Paper No. 8. New York, UNDP, Human Development Report Office. 28:<br />

2029-2049.<br />

—— (2000). “Human Development and Economic Sustainability.” World Development 28(12):<br />

2029-2049.<br />

Aschauer, D. A. and Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. (1988). Is public expenditure productive?<br />

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.<br />

Atkinson, G. and T. Oleson (1996). “Urban sprawl as a path of dependent process.” Journal of<br />

Economic Issues 30(6): 609-.<br />

Atkinson, R. (2001). “The Emerging "Urban Agenda" and the European Spatial Development<br />

Perspective: Towards and EU Urban Policy?” European Planning Studies 9(3).<br />

Augé, M. (1995). Non-Places - Introduction to an Anthropology of Supermodernity. New York,<br />

Verso Books.<br />

Avery, G. and F. Cameron (1998). The Enlargement of the European Union. Sheffield, Sheffield<br />

Academic Press.<br />

Baar, K. (2002). Legislative Tools for Preserving Town Centers and Halting the Spread of<br />

Hypermarkets and Malls Outside of Cities - Land Use Legislation and Controls of<br />

Conflicts of Interests in Land Use Decision Making. New York, Institute for<br />

Transportation and Development Policy.<br />

Bache, I. (1998). The politics of European Union regional policy: multi-level governance or<br />

flexible gatekeeping? Sheffield, England, Sheffield Academic Press.<br />

Baeten, G. (2000). “The tragedy of the highway: Empowerment, disempowerment and the<br />

politics of sustainability discourses and practices.” European Planning Studies 8(1): 69-<br />

86.<br />

Baeyens, H. (1997). Capital Regions in Europe. European Space - Baltic Space - Polish Space,<br />

Part One. A. Kuklinski. Warsaw, European Institute for Regional and Local<br />

Development, University of Warsaw. 3: 221-231.<br />

Bailey, N. and I. Turok (2001). “Central Scotland as a Polycentric Urban Region: Useful<br />

Plannign Concept or Chimera?” Urban Studies 38(4): 697-715.<br />

Baker, S., M. Kousis, et al., Eds. (1997). The politics of sustainable development: theory, policy


456<br />

and practice within the European Union. Global environmental change series. London ;<br />

New York, Routledge.<br />

Balsas, C. (2001). “Commerce and the European city center: Modernization, regeneration and<br />

management.” European Planning Studies 9(5).<br />

Banister, D. and J. Berechman (1993). Transport in a unified Europe: policies and challenges.<br />

Amsterdam ; New York, North-Holland.<br />

Banister, D., R. Capello, et al., Eds. (1995). European Transport and Communications Networks.<br />

New York, John Wiley and Sons.<br />

Banister, D., Ed. (1998). Transport and the Environment. London, E & F Spon.<br />

Banister, D. (2000). “Sustainable Urban Development and Transport - a Eurovision for 2020.”<br />

Transport Reviews 20(1): 113-130.<br />

Banister, D., K. Dreborg, et al. (2000). “Transport Policy Scenarios for the EU: 2020 Images of<br />

the Future.” Innovation 13(1): 27-45.<br />

Banister, D. (2000). “Sustainable Mobility.” Built Environment 26(3 Sustainable Mobility in the<br />

EU): 175-186.<br />

Barnes, J. (2001). Statement of James N. Barnes to the Trans-European Transport Networks<br />

Conference. Strasbourg, France, Friends of the Earth and CEE Bankwatch Network.<br />

Barter, P. (1998). Transport and Urban Poverty in Asia: A Brief Introduction to the Key Issues.<br />

Paper prepared for the Regional Symposium on Urban Poverty in Asia held in Fukuoka,<br />

Japan, 27-October 1998, Organized by the UN Centre for Regional Development,<br />

UNCHS, and the Regional Office for Asia for the Urban Management Program.<br />

Baudrillard, J. (1988). America. London, Verso.<br />

Beck, U. (1992). Risk Society: Towards a New Modernity. London, Sage.<br />

—— (1997). The Reinvention of Politics: Rethinking Modernity in the Global Social Order.<br />

Cambridge, Polity.<br />

—— (2001). “The fight for a cosmopolitan future.” New Statesman(5 November 2001): 33-.<br />

Beck, U., A. Giddens, et al., Eds. (1994). Reflexive Modernization: Politics, Tradition and<br />

Aesthetics in the Modern Social Order. Cambridge, Polity.<br />

Beckmann, J. (2001a). Risky Mobility - The filtering of automobility's unintended consequences.<br />

Kopenhagen, University of Kopenhagen, Department of Sociology.<br />

—— (2001b). In view of auto risks - summarising the mobility view of the Danish auto club<br />

FDM. Paper presented at the ESA conference, Helsinki, 2001.<br />

Bengs, C. and K. Böhme (1998). The Progress of European Spatial Planning. Stockholm,<br />

Nordregio.<br />

Benkö, A. (2002). Minister promises thorough road network, open tenders. Budapest Sun. August<br />

19, 2002.<br />

Bereijkian, J. and J. Dryzek (2000). “Reflexive Action in International Politics.” British Journal<br />

of Political Science 30: 193-216.<br />

Berger, G., A. Flynn, et al. (2001). “Ecological modernization as a basis for environmental<br />

policy: Current environmental discourse and policy and the implications on<br />

environmental supply chain management.” Innovation 14(1): 55-72.<br />

Berke, P. R. and M. M. Conroy (2000). “Are we planning for sustainable development?” Journal<br />

of the American Planning Association 66(1): 21-33.<br />

Bertaud, A. and B. Renaud (1995). Cities without land markets: Location and land use in socialist<br />

cities. Washington D.C., The World Bank.<br />

Bertaud, A. (1999). The spatial development of Budapest. (Unpublished note summarizing work<br />

done during a stay in Budapest from January 18 to January 28,1999). Washington, DC,<br />

The World Bank.<br />

Beuthe, M. and P. Nijkamp, Eds. (1999). New Contributions to Transportation Analysis in<br />

Europe. Aldershot, Ashgate.<br />

Biehl, D. e. (1986). The Contribution of Infrastructure to Regional Development. Final report of


457<br />

the Infrastructure Studies Group to the Commission of the European Communities.<br />

Luxembourg, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities.<br />

Bina, O., B. Briggs, et al. (1995). The Impact of Trans-European Networks on Nature<br />

Conservation: A Pilot Project. Bedfordshire, The Royal Society for the Protection of<br />

Birds.<br />

Bina, O. (1999). SEA to Date, Recent Advances and Current Priorities for Development.<br />

OECD/ECMT Conference on SEA for Transport, Warsaw.<br />

Bindseil, U. and C. Hantke (1997). “The power distribution in decision making among EU<br />

member states.” European Journal of Political Economy 13: 171-185.<br />

BirdLife International, Climate Network Europe, et al. (May 29, 2001). Open Letter to Heads of<br />

State and Government Meeting in Göteborg, Sweden 15-16 June 2001. 2001.<br />

Black, A. (1995). Urban Mass Transportation Planning. New York, McGraw-Hill.<br />

Blotevogel, H.-H. (1997). Bevoelkerung, Wirtschaft und Regionale Restrukturierung in Europa.<br />

European Space - Baltic Space - Polish Space, Part One. A. Kuklinski. Warsaw,<br />

European Institute for Regional and Local Development, University of Warsaw. 3: 35-50.<br />

Blowers, A. (1997). “Environmental Policy: Ecological Modernization or the Risk Society?”<br />

Urban Studies 34(5-6): 845-871.<br />

Bluestone, B. and B. Harrison (1982). The Deindustrialization of America. New York, Basic<br />

Books.<br />

Boarnet, M. (1997). “Highways and economic productivity: Interpreting recent evidence.”<br />

Journal of Planning Literature 11(4): 476-486.<br />

Boege, S. (1995). “The Well-Traveled Yogurt Pot: Lessons for new freight transport policies and<br />

regional production.” World Transport Policies and Practice 1(1): 7-11.<br />

Boehmer-Christiansen, S. (1994). The precautionary principle in Germany: enabling government.<br />

Interpreting the Precautionary Principle. T. O'Riordan and J. Cameron. London,<br />

Earthscan Publications.<br />

Boldrin, M. and F. Canova (2001). “Inequality and convergence in Europe's regions:<br />

Reconsidering European regional policies.” Economic Policy(32): 207-253.<br />

Bornschier, V. (1997). European processes and the state of the European Union. Zurich,<br />

University of Zurich.<br />

Bowers, C. (1992). The EC White Paper on Transport - a guide for the environmental<br />

campaigner. T&E Paper 92/8. Brussels, European Federation for Transport and<br />

Environment (T&E).<br />

Boyer, R. (1990). The Regulation School: A Critical Introduction. New York, Columbia<br />

University Press.<br />

Böge, S. (1995). “The well-travelled yoghurt pot: Lessons for new freight transport policies and<br />

regional production.” World Transport Policy and Practice 1(1): 771-781.<br />

Böröcz, J. (2000). “The Fox and the Raven: The European Union and Hungary Negotiate the<br />

Margins of 'Europe'.” Comparative Studies in Society and History 42: 847-875.<br />

Brake, K. (1997). Zu den empirischen Gehalten neuer Leitbilder der Raumentwicklung. Beiträge<br />

zu einer aktuellen Theorie der räumlich-ökologischen Planung. J. Hanisch. <strong>Berlin</strong>, Verlag<br />

für Wissenschaft und Forschung.<br />

Brand, P. (1999). “The Environment and Postmodern Spatial Consciousness: A Sociology of<br />

Urban Environmental Agendas.” Journal of Environmental Planning and Management<br />

42(5): 631-648.<br />

Bratzel, S. (1999). “Conditions of success in sustainable urban transport policy - Policy change in<br />

"relatively successful" European cities.” Transport Reviews 19(2): 177-190.<br />

Briassoulis, H. (2001). “Sustainable development and its indicators: Through a (planner's) glass<br />

darkly.” Journal of environmental planning and management 44(3): 409-427.<br />

Bristow, A. L. and J. Nellthorp (2000). “Transport project appraisal in the European Union.”<br />

Transport Policy(7): 51-60.


458<br />

Brocker, J. and K. Peschel (1988). Trade. Regional Impact of Community Policies in Europe. W.<br />

Molle and R. Cappelin. Avebury, Altershot: 127-151.<br />

Broecker, J. and H. Herrmann, Eds. (2000). Spatial Change and Interregional Flows in the<br />

Integrating Europe - Essays in Honor of Karin Peschel. Kiel, Physica Verlag.<br />

Brunet, R. (1989). Les Villes Européennes. Paris, DATAR.<br />

Bullard, R. (1990). Dumping in Dixie: Race, class, and environmental quality. Boulder, CO,<br />

Westview Publishers.<br />

Bullard, R. and G. S. Johnson, Eds. (1997). Just Transportation: Dismantling Race and Class<br />

Barriers to Mobility. Gabriola Island, B.C. and Stony Creek, CT, New Society<br />

Publishers.<br />

Burchell, G. (1991). The Foucault Effect - Studies in Governmentality. London, Harvester<br />

Whetsheaf.<br />

Burton, E. (2000). “The compact city: Just or just compact? A preliminary analysis.” Urban<br />

Studies 37(11): 1969-2006.<br />

Buttel, F. (2000). “Ecological modernisation as social theory.” Geoforum 31: 57-65.<br />

Button, K. J. (1993). Transport economics. Aldershot, Hants, England ; Brookfield, Vt., Elgar.<br />

—— (1994). Transport Policy - Ways into Europe's Future. Gütersloh, Bertelsmann<br />

Foundation.<br />

Button, K. and E. Verhoef, Eds. (1998). Road Pricing, Traffic Congestion, and the Environment.<br />

Cheltenham, Edward Elgar Publishing.<br />

Buunk, W. (1999). Trans-European Networks (TENs). The first spatial concept in European<br />

policies: Establishing a policy arena around one European spatial development issue.<br />

AESOP Congress, Bergen, Norway.<br />

Calthorpe, P. and W. Fulton (2001). The Regional City. Planning for the End of Sprawl. New<br />

York, Island Press.<br />

Campbell, S. (1996). “Green cities, growing cities, just cities? Urban planning and the<br />

contradictions of sustainable development.” Journal of the American Planning<br />

Association 62(3): 296-.<br />

Canzler, W. (2000). “Das Auto im Kopf und vor der Haustür. Zur Wechselbeziehung von<br />

Individualisierung und Autonutzung.” Soziale Welt 51(2): 191-2008.<br />

Capello, R. and A. Gillespie (1993). Transport, Communications and Spatial Organisation:<br />

Conceptual Framework and Future Trends. Europe on the move: recent developments in<br />

European communications and transport activity research. P. Nijkamp. Aldershot,<br />

Avebury.<br />

Cappellin, R. (2000). Urban Agglomeration and Regional Development Policies in an Enlarged<br />

Europe. Spatial Change and Interregional Flows in the Integrating Europe - Essays in<br />

Honor of Karin Peschel. J. Broecker and H. Herrmann. Kiel, Physica Verlag: 117-130.<br />

Carroll, M. C. and J. R. Stanfield (2001). “Sustainable regional economic development.” Journal<br />

of Economic Issues. 35(2): 469-476.<br />

Castells, M. (1989). The informational city: information technology, economic restructuring, and<br />

the urban-regional process. Oxford, UK ; New York, NY, USA, B. Blackwell.<br />

—— (1996). The rise of the network society. Cambridge, MA ; Oxford, Blackwell Publishers.<br />

—— (1997). The power of identity. Cambridge, Mass ; Oxford, Blackwell.<br />

—— (1998). End of millennium. Malden, MA, Blackwell.<br />

CEE Bankwatch Network (1997). Blueprints for Sustainable Transportation in Central and<br />

Eastern Europe: Regional Report. Krakow, CEE Bankwatch Network.<br />

—— (2000). M0 Dossier. Budapest, CEE Bankwatch.<br />

Central European Initiative (CEI), OECD, United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) and<br />

Austrian Federal Ministry for Environment, Youth, and Family (FMEYF), (1999).<br />

Towards Sustainable Transport in the CEI Countries. Vienna, Austrian Federal Ministry<br />

for Environment, Youth, and Family.


459<br />

Centre For European Policy Studies (CEPS) (1998). Investing in a Common Future: Transport<br />

Infrastructure in Central and Eastern Europe. Brussels, CEPS.<br />

—— (1999). The Prospects for Rail in the CEEC Countries. Report of a CEPS Working Party.<br />

W. Hager and W. Rothengatter. Brussels, CEPS.<br />

Cheshire, P. (1990). “Explaining the recent performance of the European Community's major<br />

urban regions.” Urban Studies 27: 311-333.<br />

Cheshire, P. and I. Gordon (1995). Territorial Competition in an Integration Europe: Local<br />

Impact and Public Policy. Aldershot, Avebury.<br />

—— (1998). “Territorial competition: Some lessons for policy.” The Annals of Regional<br />

Science(32): 321-346.<br />

Christoff, P. (1996). “Ecological modernisation, ecological modernities.” Environmental Politics<br />

5: 476-500.<br />

Clean Air Action Group and Hungarian Traffic Club (1999). White Paper on Restructuring Rail<br />

in Hungary. Budapest, CAAG.<br />

Coccossis, H. and P. Nijkamp, Eds. (1995). Overcoming Isolation - Information and<br />

Transportation Networks in Development Strategies for Peripheral Areas. <strong>Berlin</strong>,<br />

Springer Verlag.<br />

Cohen, M. J. (2001). Ecological Modernization and its Discontents. unpublished manuscript.<br />

Newark, NJ, New Jersey Institute of Technology.<br />

Cole, J. P. and F. Cole (1997). A geography of the European Union. London and New York,<br />

Routledge.<br />

Collier, U. (1996). Deregulation, Subsidiarity and Sustainability: New Challenges for EU<br />

Environmental Policy. San Domenico, European University Institute.<br />

—— (1999). Towards Sustainability in the European Union - Beyond the Rhetoric. European<br />

discourses on environmental policy. M. L. J. Wissenburg, G. Orhan and U. Collier.<br />

Aldershot, Hants, England; Brookfield, Vt., Ashgate: 81-99.<br />

—— (not dated). The implementation of sustainable development in the EU Member States -<br />

Report from the ECPR workshop in Oslo. 2001.<br />

Colliers International (2001). Real Estate Review 2001: Hungary. Budapest, Colliers<br />

International.<br />

Commission of the European Communities (1992a). Green paper on the impact of transport on<br />

the environment: a community strategy for sustainable mobility. COM (92) 46 final<br />

—— (1992b). Official Journal of the European Community No C 236/6-18. COM (92) 231<br />

final.<br />

—— (1992c). Communication from the Commission - The Future Development of the<br />

Common Transport Policy: a global approach to the construction of a Community<br />

framework for sustainable mobility. COM (1992) 494 final<br />

—— (1993). Growth, Competitiveness, Employment; The Challenges and Ways Forward into<br />

the 21st Century. COM (1993) 700 final.<br />

—— (1994). The Trans-European Transport Network. Luxembourg, Office for Official<br />

Publications of the European Communities.<br />

—— (1995). Towards fair and efficient pricing in transport - Green Paper. Policy options for<br />

internalising the external costs of transport in the European Union. COM(95)691<br />

—— (1996a). The Citizen's Network: Fulfilling the potential of public passenger transport in<br />

Europe. Brussels, CEC.<br />

—— (1996b). The Single Market and Tomorrow's Europe: A Progress Report from the<br />

European Commission. Luxembourg, Office for Official Publications of the European<br />

Communities.<br />

—— (1997a). Towards an urban agenda in the European Union. Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (1997b). Connecting the Union's transport infrastructure network to its neighbours:<br />

Towards a cooperative pan-European transport policy network. COM (97) 172 Final.


460<br />

—— (1997c). Towards a Common Pan-European Transport Policy. Luxembourg, Office for<br />

Official Publications of the European Communities.<br />

—— (1997d). Agenda 2000. Volume 1: For a stronger and wider EU. Luxembourg, Office for<br />

Official Publications of the European Communities.<br />

—— (1997e). Agenda 2000. Volume 2: The challenge of enlargement. Luxembourg, Office<br />

for Official Publications of the European Communities.<br />

—— (1998a). Communication from the Commission - Sustainable Urban Development in the<br />

European Union: A Framework for Action.<br />

—— (1998b). White Paper - Fair Payment for Infrastructure Use: A phased approach to a<br />

common transport infrastructure charging framework in the EU. COM (98) 466 final.<br />

—— (1998c). “Agenda 2000: Enlargement - Composite paper 1998: Progress made by the<br />

candidate countries towards accession.” Bulletin of the European Union - Supplement 4:<br />

1-30.<br />

—— (1998d). Trans-European Transport Network 1998 Report on the Implementation of the<br />

Guidelines and Priorities for the Future. COM (98) 614 - Pursuant to Article 18 of<br />

Decision 1692/96/EC.<br />

—— (1998e). Quarterly Status Reports. Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (1998f). Transport Infrastructure Investment Projects, Phare Programme. Brussels, CEC.<br />

—— (1998g). The Common Transport Policy - Sustainable Mobility: Perspectives for the<br />

Future. COM (1998) 716 final.<br />

—— (1999a). Glossary - Institutions, policies and enlargement of the European Union.<br />

Brussels, European Commission, Education and Culture Unit Publications.<br />

—— (1999b). Cohesion and Transport. A Communication by the Commission. Brussels,<br />

CEC.<br />

—— (1999c). Transport Infrastructure Needs Assessment (TINA) - Final Report. Vienna,<br />

TINA Secretariat.<br />

—— (1999d). An Evaluation of PHARE-Financed Transport Programmes - Final Report 1999.<br />

Report produced by TRADEMCO LtD of Greece, ITS of the University of Leeds and<br />

University of Westminster for the Evaluation Unit fo the Joint Relex Service (SCR) of<br />

the European Commission. Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (1999e). An Evaluation of PHARE and TACIS Co-Financing Programmes with the<br />

EBRD. Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (1999f). Guide to the Transport Acquis. Brussels, Commission of the European<br />

Communities, Directorate General for Transport.<br />

—— (1999g). Framework for Funding of Investments in the Field of Transport Infrastructure<br />

with ISPA. Brussels, CEC, Directorate General for Regional Policy.<br />

—— (1999h). ESDP European Spatial Development Perspective - Towards Balanced and<br />

Sustainable Development of the Territory of the European Union. Agreed at the Informal<br />

Council of Ministers responsible for Spatial Planning in Potsdam, May 1999. Brussels,<br />

CEC<br />

—— (2000a). ISPA mandate, programming and implementation: state of play. Brussels, CEC,<br />

Directorate General for Regional Policy.<br />

—— (2000b). Communication from the Commission A Review of the Auto-Oil II Programme.<br />

COM (2000) 626 final. Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (2000c). Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European<br />

Parliament - Promoting sustainable transport in development cooperation. COM (2000)<br />

422 final. Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (2000d). Status of the Pan-European Transport Corridors and Transport Areas. Vienna,<br />

TINA Secretariat.<br />

—— (2000e). Manual on Strategic Environmental Assessment of Transport Infrastructure<br />

Plans. Brussels, CEC, DG TREN.


461<br />

—— (2001a). A Sustainable Europe for a Better World: A European Union Strategy for<br />

Sustainable Development. COM(2001)264 final. Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (2001b). Introduction: Towards ‘sustainable mobility’, CEC, Directorate General for<br />

Transport and Energy (DG TREN). 2001.<br />

—— (2001c). 'Environment 2010: Our Future, Our Choice' The Sixth Environment Action<br />

Programme. Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (2001d). Commission Staff Working Paper: Integrating Environment and Sustainable<br />

Development into Energy and Transport Policies: Review Report 2001 and<br />

Implementation of the Strategies.<br />

—— (2001e). Unity, solidarity, diversity for Europe, its people and its territory - Second<br />

Report on Economic and Social Cohesion (Preliminary Edition). Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (2001f). White Paper European Transport Policy for 2010: time to decide. Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (2001g). Towards more sustainable land use: Advice to the European Commission for<br />

Policy and Action. Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (2001h). European Governance - A White Paper. COM (2001) 428 final.<br />

—— (2001i). Memorandum to the Commission on the Policy Guidelines of the White Paper<br />

on a common transport policy. Policy Guidelines. Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (2001j). Communication from the Commission to the Council, the European Parliament,<br />

The Economic and Social Council and the Committee of the Regions - The Commission's<br />

Work Programme for 2001. COM (2001) 28 final.<br />

—— (2001k). Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European<br />

Parliament - Ten years after Rio: Preparing for the World Summit on Sustainable<br />

Development in 2002. COM (2001) 53 final<br />

—— (2001l). 2001 Regular Report on Poland's Progress Towards Accession. SEC(2001)1752.<br />

—— (2001m). 2001 Regular Report on Hungary's Progress Towards Accession.<br />

SEC(2001)1748<br />

—— (2001n). Proposal for a Council regulation amending regulation (EC) No 1267/1999<br />

establishing an Instrument for Structural Policies for Pre-accession. COM(2001) 110<br />

final.<br />

—— (2001o). Ten years after Rio: Preparing for the World Summit on Sustainable<br />

Development - Communication from the Commission to the Council and European<br />

Parliament. Brussels, COM (2001) 53 final.<br />

—— (2001p). Annual Report of the Instrument for Structural Policy for Pre-Accession (ISPA)<br />

2000 [SEC (2001) 1726]. COM (2001) 616 final.<br />

—— (2002a). Trans-European Networks Background Documents/Archives: Strategic<br />

Environmental Assessment of Transport Infrastructure Plans, CEC, DG TREN.<br />

—— (2002b). Towards a global partnership for sustainable development - Communication<br />

from the Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the Economic and Social<br />

Committee and the Committee of the Regions. COM (2002) 82 final<br />

—— (2002c). ISPA in a nutshell. Brussels, CEC, Directorate General Regional Policy.<br />

—— (2002d). ISPA - State of Play 2000-2001. Brussels, CEC, Directorate General Regional<br />

Policy.<br />

—— (2002e). Amended proposals for Council Decisions concerning the specific programmes<br />

implementing the Sixth Framework Programme of the European Community for<br />

research, technological development and demonstration activities (Version 30.1.2002).<br />

COM (2002) 43 final.<br />

Commission on Sustainable Development (2001). Enclosures to the letter dates 12 February 2001<br />

from the Permanent Representative of Austria to the United Nations addressed to the<br />

Secretary-General. Environmentally sustainable transport - guidelines.<br />

Connolly, W., Ed. (1984). Legitimacy and the State. Oxford, Basil Blackwell.<br />

Conzelmann, T. (1998). “'Europeanisation' of Regional Development Policies? Linking the Multi-


462<br />

Level Governance Approach with Theories of Policy Learning and Policy Change.”<br />

European Integration Inline Papers 2(4).<br />

Copus, A. (2001). “From Core-Periphery to Polycentric Development: Concepts of Spatial and<br />

Aspatial Peripherality.” European Planning Studies 9(4): 539-552.<br />

CORDIS News (2002). Interview with Peter Kind, Director of the Research DG's Directorate for<br />

Structural Matters. CORDIS News, Commission of the European Communities.<br />

Corvers, F. and P. Nijkamp (2000). Regional Development and Interorganizational Policy<br />

Making in a Pan-European Context. Regional Cohesion and Competition in the Age of<br />

Globalization. H. Kohno, P. Nijkamp and J. Poot. Cheltenham, Edward Algar.<br />

Council of the European Communities (1999). Council Regulation (EC) No 1267/1999 of June 21<br />

1999 establishing an Instrument for Structural Policies for Pre-Accession. Official<br />

Journal of the European Communities L 161/73.<br />

—— (1999). Council Regulation (EC) No 1266/1999 of 21 June 1999 on coordinating aid to<br />

the applicant countries in the framework of the pre-accession strategy and amending<br />

Regulation (EEC) No 3906/89. Official Journal of the European Communities L 161/68.<br />

Cram, L. (1996). Integration Theory and the Study of the European Policy Process. European<br />

Union. Power and Policy-Making. J. J. Richardson. London, Routledge.<br />

—— (1997). Policy-Making in the EU: Conceptual Lenses and the Integration Process.<br />

London, Routledge.<br />

Crane, R. (1999). The impacts of urban form on travel: A critical review., Lincoln Institute of<br />

Land Policy.<br />

Crauser, G. (2000). Structural and Cohesion Funds: Objectives and driving principles in Member<br />

States - Keynote Speech delivered at the High-Level Meeting in Budapest, March 22,<br />

2000,http://europa.eu.int/comm/regional_policy/sources/speechescrauser/20000322_en.<br />

htm, last modified February 28, 2002.<br />

Cuadrado-Roura, J. R., T. Mancha-Navarro, et al. (2000). “Regional productivity patterns in<br />

Europe: An alternative approach.” The Annals of Regional Science(34): 365-384.<br />

Cunningham, G. H. (2000). Enlargement of the EU after the Nice Summit. Lecture, European<br />

Studies Center, City University of New York Thursday, Dec. 14, 2000.<br />

Dabinett, G. and T. Richardson (1999). “The European Spatial Approach: The Role of Power and<br />

Knowledge in Strategic Planning and Policy Evaluation.” Evaluation 5(2): 220-236.<br />

Danson, M. W. (1999). “Cohesion and Diversity in the European Union: Irreconcilable Forces.”<br />

Regional Studies 33(3): 259-268.<br />

Darier, E., Ed. (1999). Discourses of the environment. Oxford, Basil Blackwell.<br />

Davies, B. and R. Harré (1990). “Positioning: The Discursive Production of Selves.” Journal for<br />

the Theory of Social Behaviour 20(1): 43-63.<br />

Davoudi, S. (2001a). Polycentricity in European Spatial Planning: an analytical tool or a<br />

normative agenda? Paper presented at the World Planning Schools Congress, Shanghai,<br />

China, July 11-15, 2001.<br />

—— (2001b). Planning and the Twin Discourses of Sustainability. Planning for a Sustainable<br />

Future. A. Layard, S. Davoudi and S. Barry. London and New York, Spon Press.<br />

Dawe, S. (2002). “Strategic Environmental Assessment: A New Paradigm for the EU.” World<br />

Transport Policy and Practice 8(1).<br />

de la Fuente, A. (2000). “Convergence across countries and regions: Theory and empirics.” EIB<br />

Papers/Cahiers BEI 5(2): 25-36.<br />

De Rynck, S. and P. McAleavy (2001). “The cohesion deficit in Structural Fund Poliy.” Journal<br />

of European Public Policy 8(4): 541-557.<br />

Devall, B. and G. Sessions (1985). Deep Ecology: Living as if Nature Mattered. Utah, Peregrine<br />

Smith Books.<br />

Diekmann, A. (1995). Towards More Rational Transport Policies in Europe. Cologne, Deutscher<br />

Instituts-Verlag GmbH.


463<br />

Dierkes, M., U. Hoffmann, et al. (1992). Leitbild und Technik. Zur Genese und Steuerung<br />

technischer Innovationen. <strong>Berlin</strong>, Wissenschaftszentrum <strong>Berlin</strong>.<br />

Dierkes, M. and L. Marz (1998). Lernkonventionen und Leitbilder. Zum Organisationslernen in<br />

Krisen. <strong>Berlin</strong>, Wissenschaftszentrum <strong>Berlin</strong> Discussion Paper FS II 98-101.<br />

Dimitriou, H. (1992). Urban Transport Planning: A developmental approach. London, Routledge.<br />

DIW (German Institute for Economic Research) and EPRC (European Policies Research Centre)<br />

(2001). The Impact of EU Enlargement on Cohesion. <strong>Berlin</strong> & Glasgow.<br />

Docherty, I. (2000). “Institutional Geography and Regime Governance - The Case of Local Rail<br />

Transport Policy.” Space and Polity 4(2): 109-130.<br />

Doherty, A. and O. Hoedeman (1994). Misshaping Europe: The European Round Table of<br />

Industrialists. The Ecologist. 24: 135-141.<br />

Dom, A. (1999). SEA of International Transport Policies and Plans: Why is it not done?<br />

OECD/ECMT Conference on Strategic Environmental Assessment for Transport,<br />

Warsaw.<br />

Dora, C. and F. Racioppi (2001). The Charter on Transport, Environment and Health: Raising<br />

awareness to promote evidence-based action across Europe. Rome, World Health<br />

Organisation (WHO), Rome Operational Division.<br />

Dowding, K. (2000). “Institutionalist research in the European Union. A critical review.”<br />

European Union Politics 1(1): 125-144.<br />

Downs, A. (1962). “The Law of Peak-Hour Express-Way Congestion.” Traffic Quarterly XVI(3):<br />

393-409.<br />

—— (1992). Stuck In Traffic. Washington, DC, The Brookings Institution and the Lincoln<br />

Institute of Land Policy.<br />

Drake, W. and K. Nicolaidis (1992). “Ideas, Interests and institutionalitzation: 'trade in services'<br />

and the Uruguay round.” International Organization 46: 37-100.<br />

Drengson, A. and Y. Inoue, Eds. (1995). The Deep Ecology Movement: An Introductory<br />

Anthology. Berkeley, North Atlantic Publishers.<br />

Drengson, A. (1999). Ecophilosophy, Ecosophy and the Deep Ecology Movement: An Overview.<br />

Paper available on the World Wide Web under www.deep-ecology.org/drengson.html,<br />

last accessed 6-7-2002.<br />

Dryzek, J. (1997). The Politics of the Earch: Environmental Discourses. London, Oxford<br />

University Press.<br />

Dryzek, J. S. and L. Holmes (2000). “The real world of civic republicanism: Making democracy<br />

work in Poland and the Czech Republic.” Europe-Asia Studies 52(6): 1043-1068.<br />

Duany, A., E. Plater-Zyberg, et al. (2000). Suburban Nation - The Rise of Sprawl and the Decline<br />

of the American Dream. New York, North Point Press.<br />

Dudley, G. and J. Richardson (1998). “Arenas without Rules and the Policy Change Process:<br />

Outside Groups and British Roads Policy.” Political Studies XLVI: 727-747.<br />

Dudley, G., W. Parsons, et al. (2000). “Symposium: Theories of the Policy Process.” Journal of<br />

European Public Policy 7(1): 122-140.<br />

Dunlop, C. (2000). “Epistemic Communities: A Reply to Toke.” Politics 20(3): 137-144.<br />

Dusik, J. (2000). Interview at the REC Centre in Szentendre, Hungary, August 13, 2000.<br />

Eder, K. (1996). The institutionalisation of the environmental movement: ecological discourse<br />

and the second transformation of the public sphere. Risk, environment and modernity:<br />

towards a new ecology. S. Lash, B. Szerszynski and B. Wynne. Thousand Oaks, CA,<br />

Sage.<br />

Edwards, G. and W. Georg (1999). “Editorial: Plus ca change...?” Journal of Common Market<br />

Studies 37(Annual Review).<br />

Erdmenger, J. (1983). The European Community Transport Policy - Towards a Common<br />

Transport Policy. Aldershot, Gower House.<br />

Eser, T. W. and D. Konstadakopulos (2000). “Power shifts in the European Union? The case of


464<br />

spatial planning.” Europena Planning Studies 8(6): 783-798.<br />

European Centre for Infrastructure Studies (1996). State of European Infrastructure. Rotterdam,<br />

ECIS.<br />

European Centre for Infrastructure Studies (1999). Bottlenecks in the European Transport<br />

Networks. Rotterdam, ECIS.<br />

European Commission Transport RTD Programme - Fourth Framework Programme (2000).<br />

Environmental Aspects of Sustainable Mobility Working Paper, Thematic Synthesis of<br />

Transport Research Results. Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (2000). Efficiency and quality. EXTRA project within the European Commission's FP4<br />

Transport RTD Programme, Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (2000). Environmental aspects of sustainable mobility. EXTRA project within the<br />

European Commission's FP4 Transport RTD Programme, Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (2000). Integrated policy aspects of sustainable mobility. EXTRA project within the<br />

European Commission's FP4 Transport RTD Programme, Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (2001). Urban transport. EXTRA project within the European Commission's FP4<br />

Transport RTD Programme Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (2001). Social aspects of sustainable mobility. EXTRA project within the European<br />

Commission's FP4 Transport RTD Programme, Brussels, CEC<br />

—— (2001). Economic aspects of sustainable mobility. EXTRA project within the European<br />

Commission's FP4 Transport RTD Programme, Brussels, CEC<br />

European Conference of Ministers of Transport (1990). Transport policy and the environment.<br />

Paris, ECMT<br />

—— (1995a). European Transport Trends and Infrastructure Needs. Paris, ECMT<br />

—— (1995b). Transport infrastructure in Central and Eastern European countries: selection<br />

criteria and funding. Paris, ECMT<br />

—— (2000). Sustainable Transport Policies. Paris, ECMT.<br />

—— (2001). Road Accident Fatalities down in Europe in 2000. Press Release. Paris, ECMT.<br />

—— (2001). Transport Policy Forum "Transport Policies in the Countries of Central and<br />

Eastern Europe - A Decade of Integration: Results and Challenges" - Document No.<br />

1/REV1 (for official use). Report prepared by Mr. Wojciech Suchorzewski - Warsaw<br />

University of Technology (Poland) for Session 1. Policy Framework (Updated version).<br />

Paris, ECMT.<br />

—— (2001). Conclusions of Round Table 119: "Transport and Economic Development". Paris,<br />

France<br />

European Environment Agency (1995). Europe's Environment: the Dobris Assessment. London,<br />

Earthscan.<br />

—— (2002). Environmental Signals 2002 - Benchmarking the millenium. Environmental<br />

assessment report No.9. Copenhagen, EEA.<br />

European Environment Agency (EEA) (2001). TERM 2001 - Indicators tracking transport and<br />

environment integration in the European Union. Luxembourg, Office for Official<br />

Publications for the European Communities.<br />

European Federation for Transport and Environment (T&E) (1995). Getting the Prices Right.<br />

Brussels, European Federation for Transport and Environment (T&E).<br />

—— (1999). Response to the European Commission White Paper on Fair Payment for<br />

Infrastructure Use. Brussels, European Federation for Transport and Environment (T&E).<br />

—— (2000). Transport, infrastructure and the economy: Why new roads can harm the<br />

economy, local employment, and offer bad value to European taxpayers. Brussels,<br />

European Federation for Transport and Environment (T&E).<br />

European Investment Bank (EIB) Development of Trans-European Transport Networks: the way<br />

forward., EIB.<br />

European Parliament (1999). Briefing No 44 - Transport policy and EU enlargement. Brussels,


465<br />

European Parliament.<br />

European Round Table of Industrialists (1984). Missing Links - Upgrading Europe's Transborder<br />

Ground Transport Infrastructure. Brussles, European Round Table of Industrialists (aka<br />

Roundtable of European Industrialists).<br />

—— (1989). Need for Renewing Transport Infrastructure in Europe. Brussels, European<br />

Round Table of Industrialists.<br />

—— (1991). Missing networks: a European challenge - Proposals for the renewal of Europe's<br />

infrastructure. Brussles, European Round Table of Industrialists.<br />

—— (1992). Growing together: One infrastructure for Europe. Brussels, European Round<br />

Table of Industrialists.<br />

European Union (1997). Treaty establishing the European Community. Consolitated version<br />

incorporating the changes made in the Treaty of Amsterdam, Official Journal. C 340:<br />

173-308.<br />

—— (2001). Presidency Conclusions - Göteborg European Council 15 and 16 June 2001. SN<br />

200/1/01 REF 1. Brussels, European Union.<br />

Eurostat (1999). Statistics in Focus: Transport. Theme 7. Luxembourg, Eurostat.<br />

Eyerman, R. and O. Löfgren (1995). “Romancing the Road: Road Movies and Images of<br />

Mobility.” Theory, Culture and Society 12(1): 53-79.<br />

Fainstein, S. S. “Inequality in global city-regions.” .<br />

—— (2000). “New directions in planning theory.” Urban Affairs Review 35(4): 451-478.<br />

Fainstein, S. (2001). Competitiveness, Cohesion and Governance in Cities: A Review of the<br />

Literature. Presented at the annual meeting of the Association of Collegiate Schools of<br />

Planning, Cleveland Ohio, Nov 8-11, 2001.<br />

Faiola, A. (2002). Brazil's Elites Fly Above Their Fears - Rich Try to Wall Off Urban Violence.<br />

The Washington Post. Washington: A 01.<br />

Faiz, A. (2000). “Sustainable transport for the developing world: The social and environmental<br />

nexus.” Journal of Transportation Engineering(November / December 2000): 451-454.<br />

Falleth, E. I. (1999). Suburban growth and land actors along by-pass roads in Norway. European<br />

Planning Studies. 7: 357-371.<br />

Faludi, A. (1996). “Framing with images.” Environment and Planning B: Planning and Design<br />

23: 93-108.<br />

—— (1997). The Knowledge-Action Nexus in Strategic Planning. European Space - Baltic<br />

Space - Polish Space, Part One. A. Kuklinski. Warsaw, European Institute for Regional<br />

and Local Development, University of Warsaw. 3: 335-340.<br />

—— (2000). Fools dare where Angels fear to tread? Paper presented at the Annual ACSP<br />

Conference, Atlanta, USA.<br />

—— (2001a). Conceptualising European Spatial Planning. Shanghai, World Planning Schools<br />

Congress Shanghai, Contribution to track 15 on "Transnational planning": 20.<br />

—— (2001b). “The application of the European spatial development perspective: Evidence<br />

from the North-West metropolitan area.” European Planning Studies 9(5).<br />

Faludi, A. and B. Waterhout (2002). The Making of the European Spatial Development<br />

Perspective - No Masterplan. London, Routledge.<br />

Feiler, J. and M. Stoczkiewiecz (1999). The European Investment Bank: Accountable Only to the<br />

Market? Brussels, CEE Bankwatch Network and Heinrich Böll Foundation.<br />

Filion, P. (1999). “Rupture or Continuity? Modern and Postmodern Planning in Toronto.”<br />

International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 23(3): 421-445.<br />

Fink Hafner, D. (1999). “Dilemmas in managing the expanding EU: the EU and applicant states'<br />

points of view.” Journal of European Public Policy 6(5): 783-801.<br />

Fischer, F. and J. Forester, Eds. (1993). The Argumentative Turn in Policy Analysis and<br />

Planning. Durham and London, Duke University Press.<br />

Fischer, F. and M. A. Hajer (1999). Living with nature: environmental politics as cultural


466<br />

discourse. Oxford ; New York, Oxford University Press.<br />

Fischer, T. B. (1999). “The consideration of sustainablity aspects in transport infrastructure<br />

related policies, plans and programmes: A comparative analysis of North West England,<br />

Noord-Holland and Brandenburg-<strong>Berlin</strong>.” Journal of Environmental Planning and<br />

Management. 42(2): 189-219.<br />

—— (2002). Strategic Environmental Assessment in Transport and Land Use Planning.<br />

London, Earthscan.<br />

Fleischer, T. (2000). Initial Scoping Phase of a Strategic Environmental Assessment (SEA) of the<br />

Multi-Modal Transport Corridors Warsaw - Budapest. Final Draft of the In-Country<br />

Scoping Report. Hungary, Szentendre, Regional Environmental Centre.<br />

—— (1998). Rationality and Power: Democracy in Practice. Chicago, University of Chicago<br />

Press.<br />

—— (2000). “Habermas and Foucault: thinkers for civil society?” British Journal of Sociology<br />

49(2).<br />

—— (2001). Making Social Science Matter: Why social inquiry fails and how it can succeed<br />

again. New York, Cambridge University Press.<br />

Foglesong, R. E. (1986). Planning the Capitalist city. Princeton, N.J., Princeton University Press.<br />

—— (1996). Planning the Capitalist City. Readings in Planning Theory. S. Campbell and S.<br />

Fainstein. Cambridge, MA, Blackwell.<br />

Ford, R. and P. Poret (1991). “Infrastructure and Private Sector Productivity.” Economic Studies<br />

17: 63-98.<br />

Forester, J. (1989). Planning in the Face of Power. Berkeley, University of California Press.<br />

Foucault, M. (1970). The order of things: An archaeology of the human sciences. London,<br />

Tavistock.<br />

—— (1971). L'Ordre du Discours. Paris, Gallimard.<br />

—— (1976). The History of Sexuality. Harmondsworth, Pengiun.<br />

—— (1977). Discipline and Punish: The Birth of the Prison. New York, Pantheon Books.<br />

Friedmann, J. (1987). Planning in the Public Domain: From Knowledge to Action. Princeton,<br />

New Jersey, Princeton University Press.<br />

Friedrich, A., M. Tappe, et al. (2000). “A new approach to EU policy-making? The Auto Oil I<br />

Programme.” Journal of European Public Policy 7(4): 593-612.<br />

Friis, L. and A. Murphy (1999). “The European Union and Central and Eastern Europe:<br />

Governance and boundaries.” Journal of Common MArket Studies 37(2): 211-232.<br />

Gannon, C. and Z. Liu (1997). Poverty and Transport (World Bank Discussion Paper No. TWU-<br />

30). Washington, DC, The World Bank.<br />

Gantelet, G. and D. Avraam (200). Transport: the Commission formulates the political guidelines<br />

of the White Paper on the future of the common transport policy. Brussels: 3.<br />

Gare, A. E. (1995). Postmodernism and the Environmental Crisis. London, Routeledge.<br />

Gatzweiler, H.-P. and W. Goermar (2000). From Vision to Action: Spatial Development in<br />

Europe and Around the Baltic Sea. Spatial Change and Interregional Flows in the<br />

Integrating Europe - Essays in Honor of Karin Peschel. J. Broecker and H. Herrmann.<br />

Kiel, Physica Verlag: 29-40.<br />

Gerondeau, C. (1997). Transport in Europe. Boston, Artec House.<br />

Giannopoulos, G. A. and A. E. Gillespie (1993). Transport and communications innovation in<br />

Europe. London and New York, Belhaven Press ;.<br />

Gibson-Graham, J. K., S. A. Resnick, et al., Eds. (2001). Re/presenting Class: essays in<br />

postmodern Marxism. Durham, N.C., Duke University Press.<br />

Giddens, A. (1990). The Consequences of Modernity. Palo Alto, Stanford University Press.<br />

—— (1998). The Third Way: The Renewal of Social Democracy. Cambridge, Polity Press.<br />

Gillespie, B. (1998). What is Sustainable Development in the New Europe? New Europe:<br />

Transformation and Environmental Issues. L. Mariani, M. Mascia and M. Vagacova.


467<br />

Münster, Lit Verlag.<br />

Giunta, A. and F. Martinelli (1995). The Impact of Post-Fordist Corporate Restructuring in a<br />

Peripheral Region: The Mezzogiorno of Italy. Behind the myth of European union:<br />

prospects for cohesion. A. Amin and J. Tomaney. London; New York, Routledge: xiv,<br />

334.<br />

Gleeson, B. (2000). “Reflexive Modernization: The Re-enlightenment of Planning?” International<br />

Planning Studies 5(1): 117-135.<br />

Glimstedt, H. and A. Mariussen (1998). Introduction: Moving Beyond Convergency Theory.<br />

Nordic Institutions and Regional Development in a Globalised World. A. Mariussen.<br />

Stockholm, Nordregio.<br />

GM (2000). Széchenyi Plan - Pillars of the Future. Hungary's Development Plan. Budapest,<br />

Ministry of Economic Affairs (Gazdasági Minisztériumból - GM), Republic of Hungary.<br />

Goldsmith, M. (1993). “The Europeanisation of Local Government.” Urban Studies 30(10): 683-<br />

699.<br />

Gouldson, A. and J. Murphy (1996). “Ecological Modernization and the European Union.”<br />

Geoforum 27(1): 11-21.<br />

Grabbe, H. and K. Hughes (1998). Enlarging the EU Eastwards. London, Royal Institute of<br />

International Affairs.<br />

Graham, B. and M. Hart (1999). “Cohesion and Diversity in the European Union: Irreconcilable<br />

Forces?” Regional Studies 33(3): 259-268.<br />

Gramlich, E. (1994). “Infrastructure Investment: A Review Essay.” Journal of Economic<br />

Literature 17: 1176-1196.<br />

Grant-Muller, S. M., P. Mackie, et al. (2001). “Economic appraisal of European transport<br />

projects: the state-of-the-art revisited.” Transport Reviews 21(2): 237-261.<br />

Greenaway, J. and A. Grantham (2000). “Transport Policy Paradigms at the Local Level: The<br />

Norwich Inner Ring Road.” Public Administration 78(4): 815-833.<br />

Greene, D., D. Jones, et al., Eds. (1997). The Full Costs and Benefits of Transportation:<br />

Contributions to theory, method and management. <strong>Berlin</strong>, Springer Verlag.<br />

Grieco, M., L. Pickup, et al. (1989). Gender, Transport and Employment. Aldershot, Avebury<br />

Press.<br />

Gual, J. (1999). “Deregulation, integration and market structure in European banking.” EIB<br />

papers 4(2).<br />

Gutierrez, J. and P. Urbano (1996). “Accessibility in the European Union: the impact of the trans-<br />

European Road Network.” Journal of Transport Geography 4(1): 15-25.<br />

Gutierrez, J., R. Gonzales, et al. (1996). “The European High Speed Train Network: Predicted<br />

effects on accessibility patterns.” Journal of Transport Geography 4(4): 227-238.<br />

Gutiérrez, J. and G. Gómez (1999). “The impact of orbital motorways on intra-metropolitan<br />

accessibility: the case of Madrid's M-40.” Journal of Transport Geography 7: 1-15.<br />

Haas, E. (1958). The uniting of Europe: Political, social and economic forces, 1950-1957.<br />

Stanford, Stanford University Press.<br />

—— (1968). Beyond the Nation State: Functionalism and International Organization. Stanford,<br />

Stanford University Press.<br />

Haas, P. M. (1992). “Introduction: Epistemic Communities and International Policy<br />

Coordination.” International Organization 46(1): 1-35.<br />

Habermas, J. (1976). Legitimation Crisis. London, Heinemann.<br />

—— (1984). The theory of communicative action. Boston, Beacon Press.<br />

Hajer, M. (1995). The Politics of Environmental Discourse: Ecological Modernization and the<br />

Policy Process. Oxford, Clarendon Press.<br />

Hajer, M. and W. Zonneveld (2000). “Spatial planning in the network society - rethinking the<br />

principles of planning in the Netherlands.” European Planning Studies 8(3): 337-355.<br />

Hall, P. (n.d.). Christaller for a Global Age: Redrawing the Urban Hierarchy. Research Bulletin


468<br />

59. http://www.lboro.ac.uk/gawc/rb/rb59.html, accessed 3-18-2002, Globalization and<br />

World Cities Study Group and Network (GawC).<br />

Hamilton, K., L. Jenkins, et al. (1991). Women and Transport: Bus deregulation in West<br />

Yorkshire. Bradford, University of Bradford.<br />

Hamilton, K. (2000). Gender and Transport in Developed Countries. Schloss Glienicke, <strong>Berlin</strong>,<br />

Germany, 10 - 12 January 2001, Gender & Environment International Workshop,<br />

organized by the German Environment Ministry, the Heinrich Böll Foundation and<br />

UNED Forum.<br />

Hank, D. (1995). “A broader context for transportation planning.” Journal of the American<br />

Planning Association 61(1): 7.<br />

Harlander, T. (1998). “Stadtplanung und Stadtentwicklung in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland:<br />

Entwicklungsphasen seit 1945.” DISP(132): 4-.<br />

Harper, K. (2001). “Introduction: The environment as master narrative; Discourse and identity in<br />

environmental problems.” Anthropological quarterly 74(3): 101-104.<br />

Harré, R., J. Brockmeier, et al. (1999). Greenspeak: a study of environmental discourse. London,<br />

Sage.<br />

Harrison, B. (1988). The Great U-Turn: Corporate Restructuring and the Polarizing of America.<br />

New York, Basic Books.<br />

—— (1994). Lean and Mean: The Changing Landscape of Corporate Power in the Age of<br />

Flexibility. New York, Basic Books.<br />

Hart, M. (1998). Convergence, cohesion and regionalism: contradictory trends in the new Europe.<br />

Modern Europe: Place, Culture and Identity. B. Graham. London, Arnold: 164-185.<br />

Harvey, D. (1985). The Urbanization of Capital. Oxford, Basil Blackwell.<br />

—— (1989). The Condition of Postmodernity. Oxford, UK and Cambridge, MA, Blackwell.<br />

—— (1996). Justice, nature, and the geography of difference. Cambridge, Mass. ; Oxford,<br />

Blackwell Publishers.<br />

—— (1997). The Environment of Justice. The Urbanization of Injustice. A. Merrifield and E.<br />

Swyngedouw. New York, New York University Press: 65-97.<br />

Hayward, T. (1994). Ecological Thought: An Introduction. Cambridge, Polity.<br />

Häußermann, H. and W. Siebel (1995). Dienstleistungsgesellschaften. Frankfurt, Edition<br />

Suhrkamp.<br />

Heal, G. M. (2000). Interpreting Sustainability. Sustainability: Dynamics and Uncertainty. G.<br />

Chilinsky, G. M. Heal and A. Vercelli. London, Kluver Academic Publishers.<br />

Healey, P. (1992). “Planning through debate: the communicative turn in planning theory.” Town<br />

Planning Review 63(2): 143-162.<br />

—— (1992). “A Planners Day.” Journal of the American Planning Association 58(1): 9-21.<br />

—— (1997). Collaborative planning: shaping places in fragmented societies. London,<br />

Macmillan Press.<br />

Healey, P. and R. Williams (1993). “European Urban Planning Systems: Diversity and<br />

Convergence.” Urban Studies 30(4/5): 701-720.<br />

Healey, P. and J. Hillier (1996). “Communicative micropolitics: A Story of Claims and<br />

Discourses.” International Planning Studies 1(2): 165-185.<br />

Healey, P., S. Khakee, et al. (1999). “European developments in strategic spatial planning.”<br />

European Planning Studies 7(3): 339-355.<br />

Hebbert, M. (2000). Transpennine: imaginative geographies of an interregional corridor: 379-<br />

392.<br />

Hegedüs, J. and É. Várhegyi The crisis in housing financing in the 1990s in Hungary. Budapest.<br />

HELCOM (2000). Transport-Sector Investment Decision-Making in the Baltic Sea Region. Baltic<br />

Sea Environmental Proceedings No. 79. W. Hook, D. Peters, M. Stoczkiewicz and W.<br />

Suchorzewsky. <strong>Berlin</strong> and Helsinki, Federal Environmental Agency (Umweltbundesamt)<br />

and Helsinki Commission (HELCOM).


469<br />

Henderson, K., Ed. (1999). Back to Europe: Central and Eastern Europe and the European Union.<br />

London and Philadelphia, UCL Press.<br />

Hey, C., T. Pfeiffer, et al. (1996). The Economic Impact of Motorways in the Peripheral Regions<br />

of the EU. Freiburg, Institute for Regional Studies in Europe (EURES).<br />

Hillier, B. (1999). “The common language of space: a way of looking at the social, economic and<br />

environmental functioning of cities on a common basis.” Journal of Environmental<br />

Sciences 11(3): 344-349.<br />

Hine, J. (2000). “Integration, integration, integration ... Planning for sustainable and integrated<br />

transport systems in the new millenium (Editorial).” Transport Policy(7): 175-177.<br />

Hitchens, D. (1997). “Environmental policy and the implications for competitiveness in the<br />

regions of the EU.” Regional Studies 31(8): 8-.<br />

Hix, S. (1998). “The Study of the European Union II: the "New Governance" Agenda and Its<br />

Rival.” Journal of European Public Policy 5(1): 38-65.<br />

Hoffmann, U. and L. Marz (1992). Leitbildperspektiven. Technische Innovationen zwischen<br />

Vorstellung und Verwirklichung. Streifzüge ins Übermorgen. Science Fiction und<br />

Zukunftsforschung. K. Burmeister and K. Steinmüller. Weinheim/Basel.: 197-222.<br />

—— (2000). Leitbild und Leitbildorientierung. Sommerakademie der Arbeitsgruppe<br />

Zukunftstechnologien der Grünen Akademie, Bildungshaus Kloster Neustift.<br />

Hohnmeyer, R., L. Ottinger, et al. (1997). Social Costs and Sustainability. Valuation and<br />

Implementation in the Energy and Transport Sector. <strong>Berlin</strong>.<br />

Holmes, H. (1997). Just and Sustainable Communities. Just Transportation: Dismantling Race<br />

and Class Barriers to Mobility. R. Bullard and G. S. Johnson. Gabriola Island, B.C. and<br />

Stony Creek, CT, New Society Publishers.<br />

Hooghe, L. (1998). “EU Cohesion Policy and Competing Models of European Capitalism.”<br />

Journal of Common Market Studies 36(4): 457-477.<br />

Hooghe, L. and G. Marks (2001a). Multi-level governance and European integration. Lanham,<br />

MD, Rowman & Littlefield Publishers.<br />

—— (2001b). “Types of multi-level Governance.” European Integration online Papers (EIoP)<br />

5(11).<br />

Hook, W. (1996). Counting on Cars, Counting out People - A Critique of the World Bank's<br />

Economic Assessment Procedures for the Transport Sector and Their Environmental<br />

Implications. New York, Institute for Transportation and Development Policy.<br />

—— (1998a). “Hungary's M3 Highway: Multilateral Development Banks undercutting each<br />

other's objectives.” World Transport Policy and Practice.<br />

—— (1998b). Transport and Sustainable Human Settlements: A UNDP Policy Overview. New<br />

York, UNDP.<br />

—— (1999). “The political economy of post-transition transportation policy in Hungary.”<br />

Transport Policy 6: 207-224.<br />

Hook, W. and D. Peters (1999). Major Transportation Infrastructure Investment Decision-<br />

Making, and Its Impact on the Long-Term Sustainability of the Baltic Sea. Helcom PITF<br />

Project #298 25 161. W. Suchorzewsky and M. Stoczkeiwicz. <strong>Berlin</strong>, Umweltbundesamt.<br />

Hoorn, T. v. d. (2000). Country experience: Netherlands. Paris, ECMT-OECD.<br />

Huber, J. (2000). “Towards Industrial Ecology: Sustainable Development as a Concept of<br />

Ecological Modernization.” Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning 2: 269-285.<br />

Hughes, J., G. Sasse, et al. (2001). “The regional deficit in eastward enlargement of the European<br />

Union: Top down policies and bottom up reactions.” ESRC "One Europe or several?"<br />

Programme.<br />

Huntington, S. P. (1993). “The Clash of Civilizations?” Foreign Affairs.<br />

Hurst, C., J.-F. Thisse, et al. (2000). “What diagnosis for Europe's ailing regions?” EIB<br />

Papers/Cahiers BEI 5(2): 9-30.<br />

HVB Expertise (2001). Real Estate Market Overview: Warehousing and Distribution - Budapest


470<br />

Area. Munich, HVB Expertise GmbH.<br />

IAB/DIW (2001). Neue Bundesländer. Einflussfaktoren der Regionalentwicklung.<br />

Frankfurt/MAin, (KfW) Kreditanstalt für Wiederaufbau.<br />

Ihlanfeldt, K. and D. Sjoquist (1998). “The Spatial Mismatch Hypothesis: A review of recent<br />

studies and their implications for welfare reform.” Housing Policy Debate 9: 849-892.<br />

INFRAS/IWW (2000). External costs of transport (accidents, environmental and congestion<br />

costs) in western Europe. Study on behalf of the International Railway Union. Paris and<br />

Zurich, INFRAS and IWW University of Karlsruhe.<br />

Innes, J. (1995). “Planning theory's emerging paradigm: communicative action and interactive<br />

practice.” Journal of Planning Education and Research 14(3): 183-90.<br />

Instytut na Rzecz Ekorozwojo (Institute for Sustainable Development) (1996). Alternatywa<br />

polityka transportowa (Alternative Transport Policy). Warsaw: 2 volumes.<br />

Jaakson, R. (2000). “Supra-national spatial planning of the Baltic Sea region and competing<br />

narratives for tourism.” European Planning Studies 8(5): 565-579.<br />

Jacobs, M. (1991). The Green Economy Environment, Sustainable Development and the Politics<br />

of the Future. London, Pluto Press.<br />

—— (1988). Ökologische Modernisierung. Optionen und Restriktionen präventiver<br />

Umweltpolitik. Prävantive Umweltpolitik. U. Simonis. Frankfurt/Main, Campus Verlag:<br />

13-26.<br />

—— (1997). The political system's capacity for environmental policy. National Environmental<br />

Policies: A Comparative Study of Capacity Building. M. Jänicke and H. Weidner. <strong>Berlin</strong>,<br />

Heidelberg, New York, Springer Verlag.<br />

Jänicke, M. and H. Weidner, Eds. (1997). National Environmental Policies: A Comparative Study<br />

of Capacity Building. <strong>Berlin</strong>, Heidelberg, New York, Springer Verlag.<br />

Jensen, M. (1999). “Passion and Heart in transport - a sociological analysis on transport<br />

behaviour.” Transport Policy 6: 19-33.<br />

Jensen, O. B. and T. Richardson (2001). “Nested visions: New rationalities of space in European<br />

spatial planning.” Regional Studies 35(8): 703-717.<br />

Jessop, B. and N.-L. Sum (2001). “Pre-Disciplinary and Post-Disciplinary Perspectives.” New<br />

Political Economy 6(1): 89-101.<br />

John, P. (2000). “The Europeanisation of sub-national governance.” Urban studies 37(5/6): 877-<br />

894.<br />

Johnson, D. and C. Turner (1997). Trans-European Networks – The Political Economy of<br />

Integrating Europe’s Infrastructure, Macmillan.<br />

Jordan, A. (1998). “EU Environmental Policy at 25: The Politics of multinational governance.”<br />

Environment 40(1): 14-20.<br />

Judge, D., G. Stoker, et al., Eds. (1995). Theories of Urban Politics. Thousand Oaks, Sage.<br />

Judge, E. (2000). “The regional and environmental dimension of Polish motorway policy.”<br />

Regional Studies 34(5): 488-493.<br />

Kain, J. (1968). “Housing Segregation, Negro Employment, and metropolitan decentralization.”<br />

Quarterly Journal of Economics 82: 175-197.<br />

—— (1994). “The spatial mismatch hypothesis: Three decades later.” Housing Policy Debate<br />

3: 371-462.<br />

Kaiser, J. (2000). “Gaia hypothesis to get some respect?” Nature 406(6797): 685.<br />

Keim, K.-D. (1997). “Die europäische Bedeutung <strong>Berlin</strong>-Brandenburgs in seinen räumlichen<br />

Beziehungen mit Polen.”: 232-251.<br />

Kenworthy, J. and F. Laube (1999). “Patterns of automobile dependence in cities: an international<br />

overview of key physical and economic dimensions with some implications for urban<br />

policy.” Transportation Research Record A 1999: 691-723.<br />

Keohane, R. O. and S. Hoffmann, Eds. (1991). The New European Community: Decisionmaking<br />

and Institutional Change. Boulder, Westview Press.


471<br />

Kesselring, S. (2001). Mobile Politik - Ein soziologischer Blick auf Verkehrspolitik in München.<br />

<strong>Berlin</strong>, Edition Sigma.<br />

King, G., R. O. Keohane, et al. (1994). Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Inference in<br />

Qualitative Research. Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press.<br />

Kiriazidis, T. (1994). European Transport: Problems and Policies. Aldershot, Avebury.<br />

Kloosterman, R. and S. Musterd (2001). “The Polycentric Urban Region: Towards a Research<br />

Agenda.” Urban Studies 38(4): 623-633.<br />

Kozeltsev, M. (1998). Transition to sustainability of the Central and Eastern European Countries.<br />

New Europe: Tranformation and Environmental Issues. L. Mariani, M. Mascia and M.<br />

Vagacova. Münster, LIT Verlag: 133-144.<br />

KÖVIM (1996). Transport Policy of the Government of the Republic of Hungary. Budapest,<br />

Ministry of Transport, Communication and Water (Közlekedési és Vízügyi Minisztérium,<br />

KÖVIM), Republic of Hungary.<br />

—— (2001). Transport Policy - The TINA Network, Ministry of Transport, Communication<br />

and Water (Közlekedési és Vízügyi Minisztérium, KÖVIM), Republic of Hungary.<br />

Krätke, S. (1991). Strukturwandel der Städte: Städtesystem und Grundstücksmarkt in der<br />

postfordistischen Ära. Frankfurt am Main, Campus.<br />

—— (2001). “Strengthening the Polycentric Urban System in Europe: Conclusions from the<br />

ESDP.” European Planning Studies 9(1): 105-116.<br />

Krugman, P. (1991). Geography and Trade. Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.<br />

Kuhn, T. (1970). The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. Chicago, University of Chicago Press.<br />

Kuklinski, A., Ed. (1997a). European Space - Baltic Space - Polish Space, Part One. Europe<br />

2010. Warsaw, European Institute for Regional and Local Development, University of<br />

Warsaw.<br />

—— (1997b). Interregional Disparities in Europe: A Problem of the 21st Century? European<br />

Space - Baltic Space - Polish Space, Part One. A. Kuklinski. Warsaw, European Institute<br />

for Regional and Local Development, University of Warsaw. 3: 197-208.<br />

—— (1997c). The New European Space (N.E.S.) - Experiences and Prospects. European<br />

Space - Baltic Space - Polish Space, Part One. A. Kuklinski. Warsaw, European Institute<br />

for Regional and Local Development, University of Warsaw. 3: 312-330.<br />

Kunzmann, K. R. and M. Wegener (1991). The Pattern of Urbanisation in Western Europe, 1960-<br />

1990. IRPUD Working Papers No. 28. Dortmund, Institut für Raumplanung (IRPUD).<br />

Kunzmann, K. R. (1996). “Euro-megalopolis or Themepark Europe? Scenarios for European<br />

Spatial Development.” International Planning Studies 3(101-120).<br />

—— (1998). “Planning for Spatial Equity in Europe.” International Planning Studies 3(1):<br />

101-120.<br />

—— (2001). “State Planning: A German Success Story?” International Planning Studies 6(2):<br />

153-166.<br />

Kühn, M. (2000). “Vom Ring zum Netz? Siedlungsstrukturelle Modelle zum Verhältnis von<br />

Grossstadt und Landschaft in der Stadtregion.” DISP(143): 18-24.<br />

Langdon, P. (2001). “The long road to rebuilding Lower Manhattan.” Planning(4).<br />

Langhelle, O. (1999). “Sustainable development: Exploring the ethics of "Our Common Future".”<br />

International Political Science Review 20(2): 129-149.<br />

—— (2000). “Why Ecological Modernization and Sustainable Development Should Not Be<br />

Conflated.” Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning 2: 303-322.<br />

Langmyhr, T. (2000). “The rhetorical side of transport planning.” European Planning Studies<br />

8(5): 669-684.<br />

—— (2001). “The rationality of transport investment packages.” Transportation 28: 157-178.<br />

Lash, S., B. Szerszynski, et al. (1996). Risk, environment and modernity: towards a new ecology.<br />

Thousand Oaks, CA, Sage.<br />

LeGates, R. and F. Stout, Eds. (1996). The City Reader. London, Routledge.


472<br />

Lemberg, K. (1995). Decision-Making for Trans-European Links - The Danish Case. European<br />

Transport and Communications Networks. D. Banister, R. Capello and P. Nijkamp. New<br />

York, John Wiley and Sons.<br />

Lever, W. (1997). European Regional Policy and Change: The Consequences of Enlargement in<br />

the 1980s and 19090s. European Space - Baltic Space - Polish Space, Part One. A.<br />

Kuklinski. Warsaw, European Institute for Regional and Local Development, University<br />

of Warsaw. 3: 209-220.<br />

Lever, W. F. (1999). “Competitive cities in Europe.” Urban Studies 36(5/6): 1129-1044.<br />

Levy, C. (1992). The importance of gender in planning urban transport. Gender and development,<br />

a pracical guide. L. Ostergaard. London, Routledge.<br />

Linneker, B. and B. Spence (1996). “Road transport infrastructure and regional economic<br />

development. The regional development effects of the M25 London orbital motorway.”<br />

Journal of Transport Geography 4(2): 77-92.<br />

Lipietz, A. (1986). “Behind the Crisis: The Exhaustion of a Regime of Accumulation. A<br />

Regulation School Perspective on some French Empirical Works.” Review of Radical<br />

and Critical Economics 18(1): 13-32.<br />

Lipietz, A. (1992). Towards a new economic order: postfordism, ecology, and democracy.<br />

Cambridge, Polity Press.<br />

—— (1997). “The post-Fordist world: labour relations, international hierarchy and global<br />

ecology.” Review of International Political Economy 4(1).<br />

Lipshutz, R. (1996). Global civil society and global environmental governance: The politics of<br />

nature from place to planet. Albany, SUNY Press.<br />

Locsmandi, G. and K. Baar (1999). Review of regulations of urban land development., The<br />

World Bank Hungarian Subantional Development Programme.<br />

London School of Economics (LSE) (1997). Study of the socio-economic impact of projects<br />

financed by the Cohesion Fund (A Report to the European Commission). London, LSE.<br />

Lovas, Z. (2000). Eine Entscheidung und viele Fragen. Budapester Zeitung. July 17, 2000.<br />

Lovelock, J. (1979). Gaia: A New Look at Life on Earth. Oxford, Oxford University Press.<br />

—— (1988). The Ages of Gaia: A Biography of our Living Earth. Oxford, Oxford University<br />

Press.<br />

Low, N. and B. Gleeson (2001). “Ecosocialization or Countermodernization? Reviewing the<br />

Shifting 'Storylines' of Transport Planning.” International Journal of Urban and Regional<br />

Research 25(4): 784-803.<br />

Lukács, A. (2001). The EU Enlargement Process and Transport - The Case of Hungary.<br />

Budapest, Clean Air Action Group.<br />

Luke, T. (1999). Eco-Managerialism: Environmental Studies as a Power/Knowledge Formation.<br />

Living with nature: environmental politics as cultural discourse. F. Fischer and M. A.<br />

Hajer. Oxford ; New York, Oxford University Press: xiii, 269.<br />

Lumley, S. (1999). “Interpreting economics, rhetoric and sustainable development: Some<br />

implications for policy determination.” Australian Geographer 30(1): 35-49.<br />

Lynch, D. (2000). “Closing the Deception Gap: Accession to the European Union and<br />

Environmental Standards in East Central Europe.” Journal of Environment and<br />

Development 9(4): 426-437.<br />

Lyotard, J.-F. (1984). The postmodern condition: A report on knowledge. Minneapolis,<br />

University of Minnesota Press.<br />

Mackensen, R. (1997). Urban Networks, Urban Structure and the New Urban Space of Europe -<br />

A Commentary. European Space - Baltic Space - Polish Space, Part One. A. Kuklinski.<br />

Warsaw, European Institute for Regional and Local Development, University of Warsaw.<br />

3: 331-334.<br />

Majchzak (1984). Methods for Policy Research. Newbury, Sage.<br />

Mann, E. (1997). Confronting Transit Racism in Los Angeles. Just Transportation: Dismantling


473<br />

Race and Class Barriers to Mobility. R. Bullard and G. S. Johnson. Gabriola Island, B.C.<br />

and Stony Creek, CT, New Society Publishers.<br />

Mannin, M., Ed. (1999). Pushing Back the Boundaries: The European Union and Central Eastern<br />

Europe. Manchester and New York, Manchester University Press.<br />

Mariani, L., M. Mascia, et al., Eds. (1998). New Europe: Transformation and Environmental<br />

Issues. Münster, LIT Verlag.<br />

Marks, G., L. Hooghe, et al. (1996). “European Integration from the 1980s: State-Centric v.<br />

Multi-Level Governance.” Journal of Common Market Studies 34(3): 341-78.<br />

Markusen, A. (1999). “Fuzzy Concepts, Scanty Evidence, Policy Distance: The Case For Rigour<br />

and Policy Relevance in Critical Regional Studies.” Regional Studies 33(9): 869-884.<br />

Martin, R. (1999). The Regional Dimension in European Public Policy: Convergence or<br />

Divergence. London and New York, MacMillan and St Martin's Press.<br />

Martin, P. (1999). “Are European regional policies delivering?” EIB papers/Cahiers BEI 4(2): 11-<br />

23.<br />

—— (2000). “The role of public policy in the process of regional convergence.” EIB<br />

Papers/Cahiers BEI 5(2): 69-80.<br />

Mas, M. e. a. (1996). “Infrastructure and Productivity in the Spanish Regions.” Regional Studies<br />

7(30): 641-9.<br />

Massa, I. and M. S. Andersen (2000a). “Special Issue Introduction: Ecological Modernization.”<br />

Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning 2: 265-267.<br />

—— (2000b). “Ecological Modernization - Origins, Dilemmas and Future Directions.” Journal<br />

of Environmental Policy and Planning 2: 337-345.<br />

Masser, I., O. Sviden, et al. (1992). The Geography of Europe's Future. London, Belhaven.<br />

Massey, D. (1984). Spatial Divisions of Labour. New York and London, Routledge.<br />

Mastermann, M. (1970). The Nature of a paradigm. Criticism and the Growth of Knowledge. I.<br />

Lakatos and A. Musgrave. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 59-90.<br />

Maystadt, P. (2000b). “Preface [Special issue "Regional development in Europe: An assessment<br />

of policy strategies"].” EIB Papers/Cahiers BEI 5(1): 4-5.<br />

McCloskey, D. (1985). The Rhetoric of Economics. Madison, University of Wisconsin Press.<br />

McCormick, J. (1996). The European Union - Politics and Policies. Boulder, Westview Press.<br />

McGranahan, G. and D. Satterthwaite (2000). Environmental Health or ecological sustainability:<br />

reconciling the Brown and Green agendas in urban development. Sustainable Cities in<br />

Developing Countries. C. Pugh. London, Earthscan.<br />

McLafferty, S. and V. Preston (1992). “Spatial Mismatch and Labor Market Segmentation for<br />

African American and Latina Women.” Economic Geography 68: 406-431.<br />

—— (1996). “Spatial Mismatch and Employment in a Decade of Restructuring.” Professional<br />

Geographer 48: 417-431.<br />

McManus, P. (1996). “Contested terrains: politics, stories and discourses of sustainability.”<br />

Environmental politics 5: 48-73.<br />

Meadows, D. H., J. Randers, et al. (1972). The Limits to Growth. London, Earth Island.<br />

Merrifield, A. and E. Swyngedouw, Eds. (1997). The Urbanization of Injustice. New York, New<br />

York University Press.<br />

Meyerhoff, A., M. Micozzi, et al. (1992). “Running on Empty: The Travel Patterns of Extremely<br />

Poor People in Los Angeles.” Transportation Research Record(1396): 153-160.<br />

Mihok, B. (1998). Issue Paper: M0 Motorway Ringroad in Hungary. Budapest, CEE Bankwatch<br />

Network (online under http://www.bankwatch.org/publications/ missuepapers.html).<br />

Mikulic, N. and J. Dusik (1999). Recent Developments in SEA in CEE. OECD/ECMT<br />

Conference on SEA for Transport, Warsaw.<br />

Miller, H. and C. Fox (2001). “The Epistemic Community.” Administration and Society 32(6):<br />

668-685.<br />

Milton, K. (1995). Environmentalism and cultural theory: Exploring the role of anthropology in


474<br />

environmental discourse. New York, Routledge.<br />

Ministry of Transport and Marine Economy, M. (1995). Polityka Transportowa (Transport<br />

Policy: A program of Activity in the Direction of Restructuring the Transport System to<br />

Adapt to the Requirements of the New Conditions of Economic Cooperation in Europe).<br />

Warsaw, MTME.<br />

Mitric, S. (2002). Regional Features of Urban Transport in Eastern Europe and the Central Asia<br />

Region. World Bank Institute, European and Central Asia - Urban Management<br />

Workshop, Kiev, Available under http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/urban/docs/7-SM-<br />

Kiev-ECA-UT-Features.pdf.<br />

Mol, A. P. J. and D. A. Sonnenfeld “Ecological modernisation around the world. Perspectives and<br />

critical debates.” Environmental Politics(9.1(Special issue)).<br />

Mol, A. P. J. and G. Spaargaren (1993). “Environment, modernity and the risk-society: the<br />

apocalyptic horizon of environmental reform.” International Sociology 8: 431-459.<br />

Mol, A. P. J. (1995). The Refinement of Production: Ecological Modernization Theory and the<br />

Chemical Industry (PhD Thesis). Utrecht, Van Arkel.<br />

—— (2000). “The environmental movement in an era of ecological modernisation.” Geoforum<br />

31: 45-56.<br />

Mollenkopf, J. H. and M. Castells (1991). Dual city: restructuring New York. New York, Russell<br />

Sage Foundation.<br />

Mollenkopf, J. (1992). A Phoenix in the Ashes. Princeton,NJ, Princeton University Press.<br />

Mollenkopf, J. (1996). How to study urban political power. The City Reader. R. LeGates and F.<br />

Stout. London, Routledge.<br />

Moravcsik, A. (1991). “Negotiating the Single European Act: national interests and conventional<br />

statecraft in the European Community.” International Organization 45(1): 19-56.<br />

—— (1998). The choice for Europe: social purpose and state power from Messina to<br />

Maastricht. London, UCL Press.<br />

—— (1999). “Is something rotten in the state of Denmark? Constructivism and European<br />

integration.” Journal of European Public Policy 6(4): 669-681.<br />

Moucque, D. (2000). “A survey of socio-economic disparities between the regions of the EU.”<br />

EIB Papers/Cahiers BEI 5(2): 13-24.<br />

Muller, J. (1998). “Paradigms and Planning Practice: Conceptual and Contextual Considerations.”<br />

International Planning Studies 3(3): 287-302.<br />

Mulley, C. and J. Nelson (1999). “Interoperatbility and transport policy: the impediments to<br />

interoperatbility i n the organisation of tran-European tranpsort systems.” Journal of<br />

Transport Geography 7: 93-104.<br />

Murphy, J. (2000). “Ecological Modernisation - Editorial.” Geoforum 21: 1-8.<br />

Naess, A. (1991). “Politics and the Ecological Crisis: An Introductory Note.” ReVision 13(3):<br />

142-147.<br />

Naess, P. and I.-L. Saglie (2000). “Surviving between the trenches: Planning research,<br />

methodology and theory of science.” European Planning Studies 8(6): 729-750.<br />

Naess, P. (2001). “Urban Planning and Sustainable Development.” Eurpoean Planning Studies<br />

9(4).<br />

National Spatial Planning Agency (NSPA), D. M. o. H., Spatial Planning and the Environment<br />

(2000). Spatial Perspectives in Europe. The Hague, NSPA.<br />

Neumayer, E. (1999). Weak Versus Strong Sustainability - Exploring the Limits of Two<br />

Opposing Paradigms. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.<br />

Newman, P. “Transport and energy.” .<br />

Ney, S. (1998). Understanding Accessability in Transport Policy. ICCR Working Paper 401.<br />

Vienna, The Interdisciplinary Centre for Comparative Research in the Social Sciecnes<br />

(ICCR).<br />

Nijkamp, P., S. Reichman, et al. (1990). Euromobile: transport, communications and mobility in


475<br />

Europe: a cross-national comparative overview. Aldershot ; Brookfield, Avebury.<br />

Nijkamp, P., Ed. (1993). Europe on the move: recent developments in European communications<br />

and transport activity research. Aldershot, Avebury.<br />

—— (1994). New Borders and Old Barriers in Spatial Development. Altershot, Ashgate.<br />

Nijkamp, P. and J. Vleugel (1995). Transport Infrastructure and European Union Developments.<br />

European Transport and Communications Networks. D. Banister, R. Capello and P.<br />

Nijkamp. New York, John Wiley and Sons.<br />

Nijkamp, P. and J. Poot (1998). “Spatial perspectives on new theories of economic growth.” The<br />

Annals of Regional Science(32): 7-37.<br />

Nijkamp, P., S. A. Rienstra, et al. (1998). Transportation planning and the future. Chichester ;<br />

New York, J. Wiley.<br />

Nijkamp, P., C. Rodenburg, et al. (2000). “Driving Forces and Threats for sustainable Transport:<br />

Scenarios for International Transport and the Environment.” Built Environment 26(3<br />

Sustainable Mobility in the EU): 236-257.<br />

Nivola, P. S. (1999). “Are Europe's cities better?” Public Interest(137 (Fall 1999)): 73-84.<br />

Norgaard, R. B. (1994). Development Betrayed: The End of Progress and a Coevolutionary<br />

Revisioning of the Future. London, Routledge.<br />

Nygren, A. (1998). “Environment as Discourse: Searching for Sustainable Development in Costa<br />

Rica.” Environmental Values 7: 201-222.<br />

O'Connor, J. (1973). The Fiscal Crisis of the State. New York, St. Martin's Press.<br />

OECD/ECMT (1999). Conference Conclusions and Recommendations. Strategic Environmental<br />

Assessment For Transport, Warsaw.<br />

Offe, C. and J. Keane (1984). Contradictions of the welfare state. London, Hutchinson.<br />

Offe, C. (1991). “Capitalism by democratic design? Democratic theory facing the triple transition<br />

in east central europe: Comment-Reply.” Social Research 58(4): 865.<br />

Official Journal of the European Communities (1996). Decision No 1692/96/EC of the European<br />

Parliament and of the Council of 23 July 1996 on Community guidelines for the<br />

development of the Trans-European transport network. Brussels. 39.<br />

—— (1998). Decision No 2179/98/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 24<br />

September 1998 on the review of the European Community Programme of policy and<br />

action in relation to the environment and sustainable development 'Towards<br />

sustainability'. OJ C 10.10.1998. Brussels.<br />

—— (2001). Commission Decision of June 200 2001 on information and publicity measures to<br />

be carried out by the beneficiary countries concerning assistance from the Instrument for<br />

Structural Policies for Pre-Accession (ISPA) (2001/503/EC). OJ C 5.7.2001. Brussels.<br />

Olsson, L. (1999). “Steps toward an environmentally sustainable transport system.” The Science<br />

of the Total Environment(235): 407-409.<br />

Ongjerth, R. (1999). Strategy Report: Metropolitan Region of the Budapest Agglomeration -<br />

Contribution to the European Metropolitan Regions Project. Submitted on behalf of the<br />

Municipality of Budapest and the Budapest Agglomeration Development Council. P.<br />

Gauder, K. Pallai and M. Balázs-Varga. Budapest, Studio Metropolitana Urban Research<br />

Center PS.<br />

Organisation for Cooperation and Economic Development (OECD) (1992). Advanced Logistics<br />

and Road Freight Transport. Paris, OECD.<br />

—— (1996a). The Vancouver Principles for Sustainable Transport. Towards Sustainable<br />

Transportation - OECD Vancouver Conference 1996, Vancouver, OECD.<br />

—— (1996b). Report on Phase 1 of the Project of Environmentally Sustainable Transportation<br />

(EST). Paris, OECD.<br />

—— (2000a). Environmentally Sustainable Transport in the CEI Countries in Transition. Paris,<br />

OECD.<br />

—— (2000b). Managing Urban Growth. Paris, OECD Territorial Development Committee.


476<br />

—— (2002). Strategies to Reduce Greenhouse Gas Emissions from Road Transport: Analytical<br />

Methods. Paris, OECD.<br />

Oxford English Dictionary. (1989) London, Oxford University Press.<br />

Paasi, A. (2001). “Europe as a social process and discourse: considerations of place, boundaries<br />

and identity.” European Urban and Regional Studies 8(1): 7-28.<br />

Pallai, K., I. Tosics, et al. (1999). Urban Development Concept for the Municipality of Budapest<br />

II (Unpublished Report, Preparatory Phase). Budapest, Municipality of Budapest.<br />

Pallai, K. (2000). The emergence of strategic planning in the 1990s: the case of Budapest,<br />

Unpublished draft, written as input for a World Bank publication on urban government.<br />

Paterson, M. (2000). “Car Culture and global environmental politics.” Review of International<br />

Studies 26: 243-270.<br />

Pearce, D. W., A. Markandya, et al., Eds. (1989). Blueprint for a Green Economy: A Report for<br />

the UK Department for the Environment. London, Earthscan.<br />

Pedersen, T. (1998). Germany, France, and the integration of Europe: a realist interpretation.<br />

London ; New York, Pinter.<br />

Pentland, C. (1973). International Theory and European Integration. New York, Free Press.<br />

Pestman, P. (2000). Mobilization and Institutionalization in Decision-Making Processes around<br />

Large-Scale Infrastructure. European Discourses on Environmental Policy. M.<br />

Wissenburg, Goetzham Orham and Ute Collier.<br />

Peters, D. (2000). Gender and Transport in Less Developed Countries. Schloss Glienicke, <strong>Berlin</strong>,<br />

Germany, 10 - 12 January 2001, Gender & Environment International Workshop,<br />

organized by the German Environment Ministry, the Heinrich Böll Foundation and<br />

UNED Forum.<br />

—— (2001). Does Brussels help finance urban sprawl in Budapest? EU Infrastructure support<br />

seen from a critical local perspective. Paper presented at the World Planning Schools<br />

Congress, Shanghai, China, 11-15 July 2001.<br />

Peterson, J. and E. E. Bomberg (1999). Decision-making in the European Union. New York, St.<br />

Martin's Press.<br />

Pezzey, J. (1989). Definitions of Sustainability, UK Centre for Economic and Environmental<br />

Development.<br />

Pezzoli, K. (1997). “Sustainable Development Literature: A Transdisciplinary Bibliography.”<br />

Journal of Environmental Planning and Management 40(5): 577-603.<br />

—— (1997). “Sustainable Development: A Transdisciplinary Overview of the Literature.”<br />

Journal of Environmental Planning and Management 40(5): 551-576.<br />

Pierce, D. W. e. a. (1994). “The Economics of Sustainable Development.” Annual Review of<br />

Energy and the Environment 19: 457-474.<br />

Pinder, D. (1983). Regional Economic Development and Policy, Theory and Practice in the<br />

European Community. London, Allen and Unwin.<br />

Pinder, D. A., J. B. Edwards, et al. (1995). “The European Investment Bank, transport investment<br />

and European Union objectives; an exploratory analysis.” 1995 3(3): 167-178.<br />

Piodi, F. (1997). The Financing of Trans-European Transport Networks. Directorate General for<br />

Research Working Dokument Transport Series E-4. Brussels, European Parliament.<br />

Piore, M. and C. F. Sabel (1984). The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity. New<br />

York, Basic Books.<br />

Pororyles, R. and L. Giorgi (2000). Transport Policy and Research: What Future? ICCR Working<br />

Paper 403. Vienna, The Interdisciplinary Centre for Comparative Research in the Social<br />

Sciecnes (ICCR).<br />

Pócza, K. (2000). Größtmögliche ungarische Beteiligung. Budapester Zeitung. April 3, 2000.<br />

Preston, C. (1999). “EU Enlargement: Developments in 1998.” Journal of Common Market<br />

Studies 37(Annual Review): 109-111.<br />

Prud'homme, R. and C.-W. Lee (1999). “Size, sprawl, speed and the efficiency of cities.” Urban


477<br />

Studies 36(11): 1849-1858.<br />

Prugh, T., R. Costanza, et al., Eds. (2000). The Local Politics of Global Sustainability.<br />

Washington, D.C., Island Press.<br />

Pucher, J. (1999). “The transformation of urban transport in the Czech Rrpublic, 1988-1998.”<br />

Transport Policy 6: 225-236.<br />

Qizilbash, M. (2001). “Sustainable Development: Concepts and Rankings.” THe Journal of<br />

Development Studies 37(3): 134.161.<br />

Quehenberger, M. (2000). “Ten Years After: Eastern Germany's convergence at a halt?” EIB<br />

Papers/Cahiers BEI 5(1): 117-136.<br />

Radaelli, C. (1999). “The public policy of the European Union: whither politics of expertise?”<br />

Journal of European Public Policy 6(5): 757-774.<br />

Rammler, S. (2001). Die Wahlverwandschaft von Moderne und Mobilität. Zum Verkehr der<br />

Gesellschaft - Archäologie und Theorie der Verkehrssoziologie (Ph.D. dissertation).<br />

<strong>Berlin</strong>, Technical University <strong>Berlin</strong>.<br />

Rasmussen, L. (1997). Toward and ethics of sustainability. A World That Worlks: Buidling<br />

Blocks for a Just and Sustainable Society. T. Schroyer. New York, Bootstrap Press.<br />

Ratti, R. (1995). Dissolution of Borders and European Logistic Networks: Spatial Implications<br />

and New Trajectories for Service Performers, Border Regions and Logistic Networks.<br />

European Transport and Communications Networks. D. Banister, R. Capello and P.<br />

Nijkamp. New York, John Wiley and Sons.<br />

Redmond, J. and G. Rosenthal (1998). The expanding European Union: past, present and future.<br />

Bolder, CO, Lynne Rienner Publishers.<br />

Regional Environmental Centre for CEE (REC), S. E. I. (2000). SEA of VI Multi-Modal<br />

Transport Corridor Warsaw - Budapest, Scoping of Environmental Issues. Regional<br />

Synthesis Report, Final Draft. Szentendre, REC.<br />

Rein, M. and D. Schön (1994). Frame Reflection: Toward the Resolution of Intracable<br />

Controversies. New York, Basic Books.<br />

Rephann, T. and A. Isserman (1994). “New Highways as Economic Development Tools: An<br />

Evaluation Using Quasi-Experimental Matching Methods.” Regional Science and Urban<br />

Economics 24(6): 723-751.<br />

Republic of Hungary, Ministry of Transport, Communication and Water Management, (1999).<br />

National ISPA Strategy: Transport Sector. (Draft Version) Budapest.<br />

—— (2000). National ISPA Strategy: Transport Sector. (Final Version) Budapest.<br />

Republic of Poland, Ministry of Transport (2000). National ISPA Strategy: Transport Sector.<br />

Warsaw.<br />

Rhodes, M. (1995). The regions and the new Europe: patterns in core and periphery development.<br />

New York, St. Martin's Press.<br />

Richardson, T. (1996). “Foucauldian discourse: power and truth in urban and regional policymaking.”<br />

European Planning Studies 4: 279-292.<br />

—— (1997). “The Trans-European Transport Network: Environmental Policy Integration in<br />

the European Union.” European Urban and Regional Studies 4(4): 333-346.<br />

—— (2000). Environmental integration in infrastructure planning: a Foucauldian discourse<br />

analysis of the trans-European transport network. Sheffield, Sheffield Hallam University.<br />

Richardson, D. (1997). The Politics of Sustainable Development. The Politics of Sustainable<br />

Development. S. Baker, M. Kousis, D. Richardson and S. Young. London and New York,<br />

Routledge: 43-60.<br />

Richardson, T. and O. B. Jensen (2000). “Discourses of mobility and polycentric development: A<br />

contested view of European Spatial Planning.” European Planning Studies 8(4): 503-520.<br />

Rienstra, S. and D. Banister (2000). “Sustainable Mobility in the EU.” Built Environment 26(3<br />

Sustainable Mobility in the EU): 171-174.<br />

Rienstra, S. and R. Piers (2000). “Targets and Their Translation to Lower Scale Levels.” Built


478<br />

Environment 26(3 Sustainable Mobility in the EU): 187-196.<br />

Rosenbloom, S. (1993). Women's Travel Pattern at Various Stages of Their Lives. Full Circles:<br />

Geographies of Women Over the Life Course. C. Katz and J. Monk. London and New<br />

York, Routledge: 208-242.<br />

Ross, J. (1998). Linking Europe: Transport Policies and Politics in the European Union.<br />

Westport, Praeger.<br />

Rosset, B. (2000). “Contributing to regional development through project selection.” EIB Papers/<br />

Cahiers BEI 5(1): 137-148.<br />

Roy, R. (1995). Lost and Found: The Community Component of the Economic Return on the<br />

Investment in PBKAL. Annex to PBKAL: Final Report on the High-Speed Rail Project<br />

Paris/London-Brussels-Cologne(-Frankfurt)Amsterdam. Brussels, European<br />

Commission/PBKAL Working Group.<br />

Rumford, C. (2000). “European Cohesion? Globalization, Autonomization, and the Dynamics of<br />

EU Integration.” Innovation 13(2): 183-197.<br />

Ruoppila, S. (2000). Residential differentiation in socialist cities. A comparative study on<br />

Budapest, Prague, Tallinn and Warsaw. Helsinki, University of Helsinki, Department of<br />

Social Policy.<br />

Ruppert, L. (2001). Expressway Networks - Special Consideration of Traffic Safety in Hungary.<br />

International Conference "Traffic Safety - A Common Task for the Integrated Europe",<br />

Budapest, Hungary.<br />

Ruzza, C. (2000). “Environmental sustainability and tourism in European policy-making.”<br />

Innovation 13(3): 292-310.<br />

Rydin, Y. (2000). “Book Reviews: 'Discourses of the environment' and 'Greenspeak: a study of<br />

environmental discourse'.” Ecumene 7(3): 347-351.<br />

Rzeszot, U. and e. al. (2000). SEA of Multimodal Transport Corridors Warzawa - Budapeszt<br />

Initial Scoping. In-Country Scoping Report, Poland. Hungary, Szendentre, REC.<br />

Sabatier, P. (1988). “An Advocacy Coalition Model of Policy Change and the Role of Policy-<br />

Oriented Learning Therein.” Policy sciences 21: 129-168.<br />

—— (1998). “The Advocacy Coalition Framework: Revisions and Relevance for Europe.”<br />

Journal of European Public Policy.<br />

Sabatier, P., Ed. (1999). Theories of the Policy Process. Boulder, CO, Westview Press.<br />

Sachs, W. (1993). Global Ecology and the shadow of development. Global Ecology: A New<br />

Arena of political conflict. W. Sachs. London, ZED Books: 3-21.<br />

Sachs, W. (1999a). Planet Dialectics. Explorations in Environment and Development. London,<br />

ZED Books.<br />

—— (1999b). “The Virtue of Enoughness.” New Perspectives Quarterly 16(2): 10-14.<br />

Sager, T. (1994). Communicative Planning Theory. Aldershot, Avebury.<br />

—— (1999). “Rhetoric of economic rationality: The Foundation of Norwegian Transport<br />

Planning.” European Planning Studies 7(4): 501-512.<br />

Sandholz, W. and J. Zysman (1989). “1992: Recasting the European Bargain.” World Politics 42:<br />

95-128.<br />

Sayer, A. and R. Walker (1992). The New Social Economy: Reworking the Division of Labour.<br />

Oxford, Blackwell.<br />

Sbragia, A. (2000). Environmental Policy - Economic Constraints and External Pressures. Policy-<br />

Making in the European Union. H. Wallace and W. Wallace. New York, Oxford<br />

University Press.<br />

Schaeffer, K. H. and E. Sclar (1980). Access for all: transportation and urban growth. New York,<br />

Columbia University Press.<br />

Scharpf, F. W. (1999). Governing in Europe: effective and democratic? Oxford ; New York,<br />

Oxford University Press.<br />

Schintler, L. and K. Button (2000). “Women, travel and the idea of 'sustainable transport'.”


479<br />

Transport Reviews 20(3): 369-383.<br />

Schleicher-Tappeser, R. (2000). Effects of transport infrastructure and transportation costs on the<br />

development of European regions. Freiburg i. Br., Institute for Regional Studies in<br />

Europe.<br />

Schmidt, M. and L. Giorgi (2001). “Successes, Failures and Prospects for the Common Transport<br />

Policy.” Innovation 14(4): 293-313.<br />

Schneider, U. (2002). Industrieimmobilienmarkt: Die Baulust hält an. Budapester Zeitung.<br />

Budapest.<br />

Scott, A. J. (1988). New Industrial Spaces: From Division of Labor to Urban Form. Berkeley and<br />

Los Angeles, University of California Press.<br />

Seippel, O. (2000). “Ecological Modernization as a Theoretical Device: Strengths and<br />

Weaknesses.” Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning 2: 287-302.<br />

Seitz, H. and G. Licht (1995). “The Impact of Public Infrastructure Capital on Regional<br />

Manufacturing Production Cost.” Regional Studies 3(29): 231-40.<br />

Sen, A. (1987). The Standard of Living. Cambridge, UK, Cambridge University Press.<br />

Sessions, G. (1995). Deep Ecology for the 21st Century: Readings on the Philosophy and Practice<br />

of the New Environmentalism. Shambala, Boston and London, New Dimensions World<br />

Broadcsting Network.<br />

Sheller, M. and J. Urry (2000). “The city and the car.” International Journal of Urban and<br />

Regional Research 24(4).<br />

Short, J. (2001). TENs and International Infrastructure Planning. European Transport Policy for<br />

2010: Time to Decision - The Day for Debate, Brussels, European Commission.<br />

Shoup, D. (1997). “The High Cost of Free Parking.” Journal of Planning Education and Research<br />

17(1): 3-20.<br />

Sichelschmidt, H. (1999). “The EU Programme ‚trans-European networks’ - a critical<br />

assessment.” Transport Policy 6: 169-181.<br />

Siebel, W. (2000). “Wesen und Zukunft der Europäischen Stadt.” DISP(141): 28-34.<br />

Sieverts, T. (1998). Zwischenstadt. Zwischen Ort und Welt, Raum und Zeit, Stadt und Land.<br />

Braunschweig/Wiesbaden, Vieweg.<br />

Smith, J. (2000). “Enlarging Europe.” Journal of Common Market Studies 38(Annual Review).<br />

Solow, R. M. (1992). An Almost Practical Step Towards Sustainability. Invited Lecture on the<br />

Occasion of the Fortieth Anniversary of Resources for the Future. Washington, DC.<br />

Spaargaren, G. (2000). “Ecological Modernization Theory and Domestic Consumption.” Journal<br />

of Environmental Policy and Planning 2: 323-335.<br />

Sperling, D. (1995). Future Drive: Electric Vehicles and Sustainable Transportation. Washington,<br />

DC, Island Press.<br />

Spiekermann, K. and M. Wegener (1994). New Time-Space Maps of Europe - IRPUD Working<br />

Paper No. 132. Dortmund, Institut für Raumplanung, Universität Dortmund.<br />

Standing Advisory Committee on Trunk Road Assessment (SACTRA) (1999). Transport<br />

Investment, Transport Intensity and Economic Growth. London, UK Government<br />

Publications.<br />

Stawarska, R. (1999). “EU enlargement from the Polish perspective.” Journal of European Public<br />

Policy 6(5): 822-838.<br />

Stoker, G. (1988). The Politics of Local Government. Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire, and<br />

London, MacMillan Education Ltd.<br />

—— (1995). Regime Theory and Urban Politics. Theories of Urban Politics. D. Judge, G.<br />

Stoker and H. Wolman. Thousand Oaks, Sage.<br />

Stone, C. (1998). “Regime Analysis and the Study of Urban Politics - A Rejoinder.” Journal of<br />

Urban Affairs 20(3): 249-260.<br />

Study Programme on European Spatial Planning (SPESP) (1999). Working Group Report<br />

"Typology of Cities". Brussels/Stockholm.


480<br />

—— (2000). Final Report. Brussels/Stockholm.<br />

Sudhir, A. and A. Sen (1994). Sustainable Human Development: Concepts and Priorities. New<br />

York, United Nations Development Programme.<br />

Swyngedouw, E. (1993). Communication, mobility and the struggle for power over space.<br />

Transport and communications innovation in Europe. G. A. Giannopoulos and A. E.<br />

Gillespie. London and New York, Belhaven Press ;: x, 369.<br />

Szabó, F. (1999). Public-Private Partnerships in Hungarian Motorway Construction, Paper<br />

presented at the ECMT Seminar on Public Private Partnerships (PPPs) in Transport<br />

Infrastructure Financing, Paris, France, 12 January 1999.<br />

Taylor, D. B. and P. Ong (1995). “Spatial Mismatch or Automobile Mismatch? An Examination<br />

of Race, Residence and Commuting in U.S. Metropolitan Areas.” Urban Studies 32:<br />

1453-1473.<br />

Taylor, Z. (1998). “Polish transport policy: An evaluation of the 1994/5 White Paper.” Journal of<br />

Transport Geography 6(3): 227-236.<br />

Taylor, N. (1999). “Anglo-American town planning theory since 1945: three significant<br />

developments but no paradigm shifts.” Planning Perspectives 14: 327-345.<br />

Tengström, E. (1999). Towards Environmental Sustainability? A comparative study of Danish,<br />

Dutch and Swedish transport policies in a European context. Aldershot, Ashgate.<br />

Teufel, D. (1989). Gesellschaftliche Kosten des Strassengueterverkehrs (The Social Costs of<br />

Road Freight Transport). UPI Bericht Nr. 14. Heidelberg, Umwelt- und Prognose-Institut<br />

Heidelberg (UPI).<br />

Therivel, R., E. Wilson, et al. (1992). Strategic Environmental Assessment. London, Earthscan.<br />

Thisse, J.-F. (2000). “Agglomeration and regional imbalance: Why? And is it bad?” EIB<br />

Papers/Cahiers BEI 5(2): 47-68.<br />

Throgmorton, J. (1992). “Planning as persuasive story telling about the future: negotiating an<br />

electric power rate settlement in Illinois.” Journal of Planning Education and Research<br />

12: 17-31.<br />

Timár, A. (1999). The M5 Motorway Project in Hungary: A successful public-private<br />

partnership., Paper presented at the ECMT Seminar on Public Private Partnerships (PPPs)<br />

in Transport Infrastructure Financing, Paris, France, 12 January 1999.<br />

TINA Secretariat Vienna and E. Commission (1999). TINA - Transport Infrastructure Needs<br />

Assessment, Final Report. Brussels and Vienna, TINA Secretariat and European<br />

Commission.<br />

Toke, D. (1999). “Epistemic Communities and Environmental Groups.” Politics 19(2): 97-103.<br />

Transportation Research Board (TRB) (1997). Toward a Sustainable Future: Addressing the<br />

Long-Term Effects of Motor Vehicle Transportation. (TRB Special Report 251).<br />

Washington, DC, Transportation Research Board (TRB),.<br />

Turner, J. and P. Fouracre (1995). “Women and Transport in developing countries.” Transport<br />

Reviews 15(1): 77-96.<br />

Turner, T. (1996). City as landscape: a post-postmodern view of planning and design. London,<br />

Spon.<br />

Turro, M. (1999). Going Trans-European: Planning and financing transport networks for Europe.<br />

Oxford, Pergamon.<br />

Union, E. (2002). Relaunching the Danube pan-European Corridor: a bridge which unites<br />

Europeans. Press Release DN IP/02/336. Brussels.<br />

United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) (1999). Human Development Report 1999.<br />

New York, UNDP.<br />

United Nations Economic Commission for Europe (UN ECE) (1997). Vienna Declaration of the<br />

1997 Regional Conference on Transport and the Environment.<br />

ECE/RCTE/CONF./2/FINAL. Geneva, UN ECE.<br />

United Nations World Commission on Environment and Development (1987). Our Common


481<br />

Future. New York, United Nations.<br />

Urry, J. (1999). Automobility, Car Culture and Weightless Travel: A discussion paper. Lancaster,<br />

Department of Sociology - Lancaster University,.<br />

van der Meer, L. (1998). The Red Octopus. A New Perspective for European Spatial<br />

Development Policies. W. Blass. Aldershot, Ashgate: 9-26.<br />

van Geenhuizen, M. and R. Ratti (1998). Managing Openess in Transport and Regional<br />

Development: An Active Space Approach. Transport Networks in Europe - Concepts,<br />

Analysis and Policies. K. Button, P. Nijkamp and H. Priemus. Cheltenham, Eward Algar.<br />

van Houtum, H. and A. Legendijk (2001). “Contextualising Regional Identity and Imagination in<br />

the Construction of Polycentric Urban Regions: The Cases of the Ruhr Area and the<br />

Basque Country.” Urban Studies 38(4): 747-767.<br />

van Nes, A. (2002a). Road building and urban changes - A morphological and configurative<br />

explanation of how ring roads change the pattern of distribution of shops in city and town<br />

centres. Department of Land Use and Landscape Planning. As, Norway, Agricultural<br />

University of Norway.<br />

—— (2002b). Road building and urban changes - A morphological and configurative<br />

explanation of how ring roads change the pattern of distribution of shops in city and town<br />

centres. (Paper summarizing findings from the author's Ph.D. Thesis). XVI AESOP<br />

Congress "Planning in Border Regions", Volos, Greece, Agricultural University of<br />

Norway.<br />

Vanhoudt, P., T. Mathae, et al. (2000). “How productive are capital investments in Europe?” EIB<br />

Papers/Cahiers BEI 5(2): 81-105.<br />

Vickerman, R. (1991). Infrastructure and Regional Development. London, Pion.<br />

—— (1995). “Regional impacts of trans-European networks.” Annals of Regional Science: an<br />

International Journal of Urban, Regional and Environmental Research and Policy 29(2):<br />

237-54.<br />

—— (1996). “Location, accessibility and regional development: the appraisal of trans-<br />

European networks.” Transport Policy 2(4): 225-234.<br />

Vickerman, R., K. Spiekermann, et al. (1999). “Accessibility and economic development in<br />

Europe.” Regional Studies 33(1): 1-15.<br />

Vigar, G. (2000). “Local 'Barriers' to Environmentally Sustainable Transport Planning.” Local<br />

Environment 5(1): 19-32.<br />

—— (2001). “Reappraising UK Transport Policy 1950-99: the myth of 'mono-modality' and<br />

the nature of 'paradigm shifts'.” Planning Perspectives 16: 269-291.<br />

Wachs, M. (1998). Men, Women and Urban Travel: the Persistence of Separate Spheres. Los<br />

Angeles, Graduate School of Architecture and Urban Planning, UCLA.<br />

Wallace, H. and W. Wallace (2000). Policy-making in the European Union. Oxford; New York,<br />

Oxford University Press.<br />

Wallace, H. (2000). Chapter 3: Analysing and Explaining Policies. Policy-making in the<br />

European Union. H. Wallace and W. Wallace. Oxford; New York, Oxford University<br />

Press: xxvii, 509.<br />

Weale, A. (1992). The New Politics of Pollution. Manchester, Manchester University Press.<br />

Weinreich, S. (1998). The QUITS study - Quality Indicators of transport systems: external costs<br />

analysis in the QUITS-project. Paper presented at the 4th International Social Cost and<br />

Sustainability Conference, World Trade Center, New York.<br />

Whitelegg, J. (1988). Transport Policy in the CEE. London and New York, Routledge.<br />

—— (1994). Transport for a sustainable future: the case for Europe. Chichester, West Sussex,<br />

New York: John Wiley & Sons.<br />

Williams, A. (1994). The European Community. Cambridge, Blackwell.<br />

Williams, R. H. (1996). European Union Spatial Policy and Planning. London, Chapman.<br />

Willson, R. (2001). “Assessing communicative rationality as a transportation planning paradigm.”


482<br />

Transportation 28: 1-31.<br />

Wissenburg, M. L. J., G. Orhan, et al. (1999). European discourses on environmental policy.<br />

Aldershot, Hants, England ; Brookfield, Vt., Ashgate.<br />

Wixey, S. and S. Lake (1998). “Transport Policy in the EU: A Strategy for Sustainable<br />

Development?” World Transport Policy and Practice 4(2).<br />

Woodfin, T. M. (1997). “City as Landscape: A Post Post-Modern View of Design and Planning.”<br />

Landscape and Urban Planning 38(1): 130-131.<br />

World Bank (1996). Sustainable transport: priorities for policy reform. Washington, D.C., World<br />

Bank.<br />

—— (1999). Poland - Strategic Priorities for the Transport Sector (Report No 19450-POL).<br />

Washington, DC, World Bank, Infrastructure Unit, European and Central Asia Region.<br />

World Business Council on Sustainable Development (WBCSD) (2001). Mobility 2001. Geneva,<br />

WBCSD: 188.<br />

World Health Organization (1999). Charter on Transport, Environment and Health.<br />

EUR/ICP/EHCO 02 02 05/Rev.4 09009. Available on the WHO Regional Office for<br />

Europe Website: http://www.who.dk/transport/MainActs/20020321_1 (Last accessed<br />

September 20, 2002).<br />

World Resources Institute (1996). World Resources 1996-97 - The Urban Environment. Oxford,<br />

Oxford University Press.<br />

Wotton, J. (1999). “Replacing the private car.” Transport Reviews 19(2): 157-175.<br />

Wyly, E. (1996). “Race, Gender, and Spatial Segmentation in the Twin Cities.” Professional<br />

Geographer 48: 431-444.<br />

Yin, R. K. (1994). Case study research: design and methods. Thousand Oaks, Sage Publications.<br />

Zielonka, J. (2000). Enlargement and the Finality of European Integration. Cambridge, Harvard<br />

Law School, Jean Monnet Chair.<br />

Zito, A. R. (2001). “Epistemic Communities, collective entrepreneurship and European<br />

integration.” Journal of European Public Policy 8(4): 585-603.


483<br />

DEIKE PETERS<br />

EDUCATION:<br />

CURRICULUM VITA<br />

RUTGERS UNIVERSITY, New Brunswick (NJ), USA<br />

Ph.D. candidate in Urban Planning and Policy Development (January 2003)<br />

COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY, New York (NY), USA<br />

Master of International Affairs (February 1996); M.Sc. in Urban Planning (May 1995)<br />

TECHNICAL UNIVERSITY HAMBURG-HARBURG, Germany (1992-1993)<br />

Department of City Planning and Urban Design; Int’l Project ”Olympic Village Barcelona”<br />

UNIVERSITÄT DORTMUND, Germany<br />

Pre-Diploma in Spatial Planning (“Vordiplom Raumplanung,” May 1992)<br />

SORBONNE, UNIVERSITÉ PARIS IV, Cours de la Civilisation Française<br />

Diploma in French Language and Cultural Studies (May 1990)<br />

EMPLOYMENT HISTORY:<br />

TECHNICAL UNIVERSITY BERLIN, Dept. City & Regional Planning (ISR), Germany<br />

Lecturer / Researcher ("Wissenschaftliche Mitarbeiterin") (Nov. 2000 - present)<br />

GERMAN ENVIRONMENT MINISTRY (BMU) / UNED Forum, <strong>Berlin</strong> / London<br />

Consultant (Nov. 2000 - Jan 2001)<br />

INSTI<strong>TU</strong>TE <strong>FOR</strong> TRANSPORTATION & DEVELOPMENT POLICY, NY, NY<br />

Director of Environmental Programs (Dec. 1995 – Oct. 2000, full-time until Sept. 1997)<br />

Assistant Program Director for Central Eastern Europe (Sept. 1994 – Nov. 1995)<br />

RUTGERS UNIVERSITY, The State University of New Jersey, New Brunswick, NJ<br />

Instructor, Dept. of Urban Studies and Community Health (Sept. 1998 – Dec. 1999)<br />

Research Assistant, Department of Urban Planning (Sept.-Dec. 1997, Jan.- May 2000)<br />

THE WORLD BANK, Washington, DC<br />

Consultant (Summer 1998, Summer 1999)<br />

UNITED NATIONS CENTER <strong>FOR</strong> HUMAN SETTLEMENTS, New York, NY<br />

Research Assistant (January - May 1996)<br />

<strong>EUROPE</strong>AN FEDERATION <strong>FOR</strong> TRANSPORT & ENVIRONMENT (T&E), Brussels<br />

Consultant (Summer 1995)<br />

PLANQUADRAT DORTMUND, Dortmund, Germany<br />

Project Intern (Summer 1993)<br />

PUBLICATION LIST AVAILABLE UPON REQUEST<br />

For a select list of articles, papers and recent conferences & workshops, see Annex III

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!