21.01.2014 Views

THE MYTH OF SOCIAL COST.pdf - Institute of Economic Affairs

THE MYTH OF SOCIAL COST.pdf - Institute of Economic Affairs

THE MYTH OF SOCIAL COST.pdf - Institute of Economic Affairs

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

EPILOGUE<br />

Pigovian solution for an externality—a tax or subsidy imposed<br />

unilaterally on its producer—did not result in an optimal<br />

allocation <strong>of</strong> resources, because the behaviour <strong>of</strong> the consumer<br />

<strong>of</strong> the externality has to be altered as well. If an optimal<br />

allocation <strong>of</strong> resources is to result from an external diseconomy,<br />

not only must the producer <strong>of</strong>the externality take into account<br />

the costs imposed on the consumer, but the 'consumer' must<br />

also take into account the costs imposed on the producer<br />

(i.e., benefits forgone) by any reduction <strong>of</strong> his activities<br />

resulting from the tax. And the 'consumer' will not do this<br />

unless a 'tax' is imposed on him for securing the benefits <strong>of</strong> the<br />

reduction in the externality.<br />

The use <strong>of</strong> taxes and subsidies by government to correct for<br />

externalities requires not unilateral tax/subsidisation on the<br />

producer(s) <strong>of</strong> external effects but bilateral taxation/subsidisation<br />

<strong>of</strong> both the parties to the effect. In other words, the use <strong>of</strong><br />

taxes and subsidies to correct for externalities could be administratively<br />

very complex—and costly. This conclusion is<br />

discussed further in 4 (below).<br />

(Recently Pr<strong>of</strong>essors S. A. Y. Lin and D. K. Whitcomb have<br />

sought to defuse this criticism. 1 They show, in a mathematically-advanced<br />

treatment, that it would be possible in principle<br />

for government to operate a unilateral tax or subsidy scheme<br />

to correct for externalities. Their model assumes, however, that<br />

both firms and government have perfect and costless information,<br />

and also that the costs <strong>of</strong> policing are zero. The absurdity<br />

<strong>of</strong> the model is that, if these conditions were true, there would<br />

be no need for government intervention to correct for externalities. A<br />

'bargaining solution' would automatically emerge for every<br />

externality: they would all be internalised by trade.)<br />

3. Jointly-supplied external benefits and costs<br />

Many external effects have both cost and benefit elements to<br />

them—as in Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Cheung's examples <strong>of</strong> airports and<br />

neighbourhood schools (above, Section III). A Pigovian tax/<br />

subsidy solution for such externalities would be even more<br />

administratively complex—and costly.<br />

4. The administrative costs <strong>of</strong> government correction <strong>of</strong><br />

'market failure'<br />

An implicit—but clearly untrue—assumption <strong>of</strong> the Pigovian<br />

1 'Externality Taxes and Subsidies', in S.A.Y. Lin (ed.), Theory and Measurement<br />

<strong>of</strong> Externalities, Academic Press, New York, 1976, pp. 45-60.<br />

[79]

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!