21.01.2015 Views

Assessment of Fuel Economy Technologies for Medium and Heavy ...

Assessment of Fuel Economy Technologies for Medium and Heavy ...

Assessment of Fuel Economy Technologies for Medium and Heavy ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Assessment</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Fuel</strong> <strong>Economy</strong> <strong>Technologies</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>Medium</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Heavy</strong><br />

Duty Vehicles: Commissioned Paper on Indirect Costs <strong>and</strong><br />

Alternative Approaches<br />

Draft final paper, Cambridge Systematics, Inc., revised September 21, 2009<br />

Introduction<br />

This paper was commissioned by the National Academy <strong>of</strong> Sciences in support <strong>of</strong> its committee<br />

on medium-duty <strong>and</strong> heavy-duty truck fuel economy st<strong>and</strong>ards as directed by the Energy<br />

Independence <strong>and</strong> Security Act <strong>of</strong> 2007. The Academy working group is charged with<br />

identifying the potential costs <strong>and</strong> other impacts <strong>of</strong> fuel economy technologies on the operation<br />

<strong>of</strong> medium-duty <strong>and</strong> heavy-duty trucks. The paper discusses two sets <strong>of</strong> issues related to<br />

potential Federal regulations to improve fuel economy <strong>of</strong> commercial motor vehicles. The first<br />

set <strong>of</strong> issues is the potential indirect costs <strong>and</strong> benefits <strong>of</strong> commercial vehicle fuel economy<br />

regulations – i.e., effects on vehicle costs, congestion, safety transportation service, <strong>and</strong> other<br />

factors in addition to the direct effects on fuel usage. The second set <strong>of</strong> issues is the potential <strong>for</strong><br />

alternatives to fuel economy regulations <strong>for</strong> improving fuel efficiency.<br />

This paper, authored by Cambridge Systematics, Inc. (CS), examines a subset <strong>of</strong> these issues <strong>and</strong><br />

complements a companion paper authored by Eastern Research Group, Inc. (ERG). Some <strong>of</strong> the<br />

issues are addressed by both authors. For example, <strong>for</strong> congestion effects, ERG‘s paper discusses<br />

the relationship between technology <strong>and</strong> per<strong>for</strong>mance, while CS‘ paper discusses the resulting<br />

impacts <strong>of</strong> per<strong>for</strong>mance on highway congestion. The issues were divided between the two firms<br />

based on their respective areas <strong>of</strong> expertise as follows:<br />

CS Paper<br />

First subset <strong>of</strong> issues (indirect costs)<br />

Vehicle-miles traveled <strong>and</strong> the rebound<br />

effect;<br />

Vehicle class shifting;<br />

Implications <strong>of</strong> transportation service <strong>and</strong><br />

per<strong>for</strong>mance effects (with ERG input on<br />

per<strong>for</strong>mance);<br />

Congestion impacts (with ERG input on<br />

per<strong>for</strong>mance); <strong>and</strong><br />

Safety impacts (<strong>of</strong> changes in traffic<br />

volume or per<strong>for</strong>mance).<br />

Second subset <strong>of</strong> issues (alternatives)<br />

<strong>Fuel</strong> tax;<br />

Congestion pricing; <strong>and</strong><br />

Intermodal transport.<br />

ERG Paper<br />

First subset <strong>of</strong> issues (indirect costs)<br />

Fleet turnover effects;<br />

Environmental costs <strong>and</strong> co-benefits;<br />

Transportation service <strong>and</strong> per<strong>for</strong>mance<br />

effects; <strong>and</strong><br />

Safety impacts (<strong>of</strong> changes in fuel type).<br />

Second subset <strong>of</strong> issues (alternatives)<br />

Driver training.


This paper relies on findings from the literature on these issues but also includes new, sketchlevel<br />

analysis to translate literature findings (which may only indirectly address the issue) into<br />

results that directly address the issues being investigated.<br />

The key findings <strong>of</strong> this paper regarding indirect costs are as follows:<br />

Vehicle-miles traveled (VMT) <strong>and</strong> the rebound effect – The ―rebound effect‖ refers to an<br />

increase in VMT that may occur as a result <strong>of</strong> lower shipping costs caused by lower fuel costs.<br />

The additional fuel consumption would partially <strong>of</strong>fset the fuel savings <strong>of</strong> more efficient<br />

trucks. <strong>Fuel</strong> economy regulations that achieve consumption reductions on the order <strong>of</strong> 4,500<br />

million gallons (17.6 percent <strong>of</strong> current fuel use) would reduce national Class 8 fuel<br />

consumption from 25,500 million gallons annually to 21,000 million gallons. This level <strong>of</strong> fuel<br />

efficiency gain would result in an average Class 8 per-mile operating cost reduction <strong>of</strong> $0.08<br />

(considering increased vehicle costs amortized over the life <strong>of</strong> the vehicle as well as decreased<br />

fuel costs), which could lead to an increase in truck dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> a decrease in rail dem<strong>and</strong>.<br />

Using a range <strong>of</strong> assumptions regarding the elasticity <strong>of</strong> truck travel with respect to price, the<br />

increase in truck dem<strong>and</strong> due to the decrease in truck operating costs would increase fuel<br />

consumption by 500 to 1,400 million gallons, diminishing the fuel consumption reduction to<br />

3,100 to 4,000 million gallons, or a rebound <strong>of</strong> 11 to 31 percent <strong>of</strong> the initial 4,500 million<br />

gallon reduction. The decrease in rail dem<strong>and</strong>, due to the diversion <strong>of</strong> rail dem<strong>and</strong> to truck,<br />

produces an additional fuel consumption reduction <strong>of</strong> 70 to 110 million gallons, counteracting<br />

the truck rebound effect by 1 to 2 percent <strong>of</strong> initial 4,500 million-gallon reduction. The net<br />

rebound effect <strong>of</strong> the truck fuel consumption increase <strong>and</strong> the rail fuel consumption decrease<br />

is there<strong>for</strong>e about 9 to 30 percent—meaning that the actual reduction in fuel use would be<br />

about 3,200 to 4,100 million gallons (a 13 to 16 percent reduction in total truck fuel<br />

consumption).<br />

For larger fuel economy improvements (on the order <strong>of</strong> 39 percent), the rebound effect would<br />

be smaller on a percentage basis – in the range <strong>of</strong> 5 to 16 percent – <strong>for</strong> a net reduction in fuel<br />

use in the range <strong>of</strong> 32 to 37 percent. This is because the technologies used to achieve the<br />

higher fuel efficiency st<strong>and</strong>ard would be somewhat less cost-effective, raising the initial<br />

capital cost <strong>of</strong> the vehicle <strong>and</strong> leading to a lower per-mile operating cost savings compared to<br />

the most cost-effective technologies used to achieve the 17.6 percent reduction.<br />

Vehicle class shifting – The potential <strong>for</strong> vehicle purchasers to shift to different classes <strong>of</strong><br />

vehicles will depend upon the specific nature <strong>of</strong> the fuel economy regulations. However,<br />

hypothetical regulatory scenarios suggest that significant class-shifting is unlikely to occur in<br />

most conceivable situations. This is particularly true <strong>for</strong> long-haul trucks, which account <strong>for</strong><br />

nearly three-quarters <strong>of</strong> total truck fuel consumption.<br />

Transportation service <strong>and</strong> per<strong>for</strong>mance effects – Analysis in the concurrent paper<br />

developed by ERG suggests that fuel economy regulations would have no appreciable effect<br />

on vehicle per<strong>for</strong>mance. There<strong>for</strong>e, impacts on transportation service (e.g., delivery times,<br />

reliability) will be minimal or non-existent.<br />

Congestion impacts – Analysis in the concurrent paper developed by ERG suggests that fuel<br />

economy regulations would have no appreciable effect on vehicle per<strong>for</strong>mance <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e


no effect on congestion as a result <strong>of</strong> degraded per<strong>for</strong>mance. However, increased truck traffic<br />

as a result <strong>of</strong> the rebound effect could increase congestion. The effect is likely to be minimal<br />

on most roads, but could be significant at times <strong>and</strong> locations where the roadway is near<br />

capacity <strong>and</strong> where truck traffic represents a significant fraction <strong>of</strong> total traffic. An estimate<br />

using marginal per-mile congestion costs from the literature suggests that the increase in<br />

truck traffic volumes described above <strong>for</strong> the rebound effect could result in an increased<br />

congestion cost (to all road users) in the range <strong>of</strong> $0.3 to $1.4 billion nationwide.<br />

Safety impacts – Analysis in the concurrent paper developed by ERG suggests that fuel<br />

economy regulations would have no appreciable effect on vehicle per<strong>for</strong>mance <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e<br />

no effect on safety as a result <strong>of</strong> degraded per<strong>for</strong>mance. Increased truck traffic volumes from<br />

the rebound effect could be expected to cause an increase in the range <strong>of</strong> 80 to 360 fatalities<br />

per year <strong>and</strong> about 1,600 to 7,700 injuries per year nationally. An alternative estimate using<br />

marginal safety costs from the literature suggests that the increased truck VMT could result in<br />

an increased safety cost (to all road users) <strong>of</strong> in the range <strong>of</strong> $0.09 to $0.4 billion nationwide.<br />

Key findings regarding alternative approaches to reduce truck fuel consumption are as follows:<br />

<strong>Fuel</strong> tax – To achieve reductions in fuel consumption <strong>of</strong> the same order <strong>of</strong> magnitude as<br />

assumed in the analysis <strong>of</strong> the rebound effect (20 to 40 percent) is estimated to require an<br />

increase in the fuel tax on the order <strong>of</strong> $1 to $2 per gallon, which would lead to a combination<br />

<strong>of</strong> both reductions in truck VMT <strong>and</strong> increases in vehicle fuel efficiency. However, elasticities<br />

<strong>of</strong> fuel consumption with respect to fuel price are not well-documented <strong>for</strong> freight trucks so<br />

this estimate should be considered particularly uncertainty.<br />

Congestion pricing – No analysis has specifically examined the impacts <strong>of</strong> a comprehensive<br />

congestion pricing system on truck fuel consumption. Estimates <strong>for</strong> all vehicles have found<br />

modest impacts, on the order <strong>of</strong> a 0.5 to 1.1 percent reduction in total fuel consumption if<br />

congestion pricing were widely applied in the U.S., although this is based on data<br />

extrapolated from only two simulation studies. This is the result <strong>of</strong> a variety <strong>of</strong> effects,<br />

including a reduction in overall dem<strong>and</strong>, shifting <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> to less congested periods, <strong>and</strong><br />

more free-flowing traffic during peak travel periods. Analysis <strong>of</strong> cordon pricing in London<br />

<strong>and</strong> Stockholm has found very small impacts on truck fuel consumption, with minimal<br />

impacts on truck VMT but some benefits through reduced truck idling. An upper bound can<br />

be placed on the potential fuel savings from congestion pricing (or other highway congestion<br />

mitigation strategies) by estimating the total nationwide fuel ―wasted‖ by trucks in<br />

congestion. This figure is estimated to be no more than 640 million gallons, or about 2<br />

percent <strong>of</strong> total truck fuel consumption.<br />

Intermodal transport – The potential <strong>for</strong> truck-to-rail mode shifting through investment in<br />

rail <strong>and</strong> intermodal infrastructure <strong>and</strong> other incentives has not been extensively studied. One<br />

study <strong>of</strong> the Mid-Atlantic region estimated that an investment <strong>of</strong> $12 billion could reduce fuel<br />

consumption by 42 to 114 million gallons annually, at a cost <strong>of</strong> $110 to $290 per gallon <strong>of</strong> fuel<br />

saved. The findings <strong>of</strong> one study <strong>of</strong> the I-81 corridor suggest that an investment <strong>of</strong> $7.9<br />

billion could reduce fuel consumption by 145 million gallons annually, at a cost <strong>of</strong> $54 per<br />

gallon <strong>of</strong> fuel saved, while another suggests that an investment <strong>of</strong> $2.5 billion <strong>for</strong> the Norfolk<br />

Southern ―Crescent Corridor,‖ also paralleling I-81 between New York <strong>and</strong> the Southeast,<br />

could save 170 million gallons annually.<br />

- 3 -


1. Indirect Costs <strong>and</strong> Benefits<br />

Little, if any, previous research has directly investigated the effects <strong>of</strong> commercial vehicle fuel<br />

economy st<strong>and</strong>ards on the factors addressed in these papers. There is a considerable amount <strong>of</strong><br />

literature that can in<strong>for</strong>m a general assessment <strong>of</strong> potential effects. The specific effects, however,<br />

depend greatly on how the fuel economy regulation is structured, as well as on external issues<br />

such as fuel prices, economic trends, <strong>and</strong> technology development. There<strong>for</strong>e, the approach<br />

taken in this paper is to develop hypothetical scenarios that allow <strong>for</strong> examine what would<br />

happen given various fuel economy regulation structures <strong>and</strong> other key factors. The objective is<br />

to provide a ―what-if‖ assessment <strong>of</strong> the impact on fuel economy regulations on per<strong>for</strong>mance,<br />

congestion, costs, etc., rather than a definitive assessment <strong>of</strong> impacts. At a minimum, this will<br />

help determine whether or not each issue is significant enough to warrant consideration in<br />

designing a commercial vehicle fuel economy st<strong>and</strong>ard.<br />

Each issue is addressed in the following <strong>for</strong>mat:<br />

Key question – What is the key question <strong>of</strong> interest that is being investigated<br />

Background – What does the literature have to say relevant to this issue<br />

Approach – What quantification method was used to estimate potential impacts related to the<br />

key question What key assumptions are made in the analysis<br />

Findings – What are the results <strong>of</strong> the analysis under alternative hypothetical scenarios<br />

generated <strong>for</strong> this report – i.e., what impact could commercial vehicle fuel economy st<strong>and</strong>ards<br />

potentially have on VMT <strong>and</strong> the rebound effect, vehicle class shifting, etc.<br />

(ii) Vehicle-Miles Traveled (VMT) <strong>and</strong> the Rebound Effect<br />

Key Question: If fuel economy improvements reduce vehicle operating costs, will truck traffic<br />

volume increase<br />

Background: A ―rebound effect‖ in heavy-duty vehicle travel can be characterized as the extent<br />

to which cost savings from heavy-duty vehicle fuel efficiency improvements result in increased<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> truck shipping <strong>and</strong> decreased dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> rail shipping because truck travel is made<br />

less expensive per-mile due to reduced fuel costs <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e reduced truck operating costs.<br />

This increased truck travel partially <strong>of</strong>fsets the total fuel savings benefits. The rebound effect has<br />

been extensively studied <strong>for</strong> light-duty (personal) vehicle travel, but somewhat less so <strong>for</strong> freight<br />

truck travel. 1 However, a number <strong>of</strong> studies have documented relationships between price <strong>and</strong><br />

dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> truck travel. This literature is focused on long-haul freight truck movements because<br />

1) the effect is likely to be strongest <strong>for</strong> long-haul movements (due to available modal<br />

competition); 2) these movements represent the carriage <strong>of</strong> a significant volume <strong>of</strong> the nation‘s<br />

freight; <strong>and</strong> 3) these movements account <strong>for</strong> the vast majority <strong>of</strong> the medium- <strong>and</strong> heavy-duty<br />

1<br />

The National Highway <strong>and</strong> Traffic Safety Administration (NHTSA), in its preliminary regulatory<br />

impact assessment <strong>for</strong> the CAFE st<strong>and</strong>ards rulemaking, selected a value <strong>of</strong> 15 percent as their best<br />

estimate, based on a review <strong>of</strong> the literature. The assessment also concluded that this effect could<br />

plausibly range from 10 to 20 or even 25 percent (NHTSA, 2008).<br />

- 4 -


vehicle fuel consumption (78 percent). 2 Little or no research exists to provide in<strong>for</strong>mation on a<br />

rebound effect <strong>for</strong> medium-duty trucks. The sketch analysis presented herein will focus on long<br />

haul trucks, which are generally Class 8 trucks with 53-foot trailers <strong>and</strong> a gross vehicle weight<br />

(GVW) <strong>of</strong> up to 80,000 pounds.<br />

Caution should be exercised when considering the price-dem<strong>and</strong> relationships found in the<br />

literature <strong>for</strong> freight trucks. The results appear to be heavily reliant on factors including the type<br />

<strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> measures analyzed (vehicle-miles <strong>of</strong> travel, ton-miles, or tons), analysis geography,<br />

trip lengths, markets served, <strong>and</strong> commodities transported. 3 The literature does not treat<br />

differences between short- <strong>and</strong> long-run effects consistently, <strong>and</strong>, in general, presents<br />

inconsistent results across studies. To provide an envelope <strong>of</strong> potential effects, the analysis<br />

presented herein provides reasonable upper <strong>and</strong> lower bounds <strong>of</strong> potential effects as well as a<br />

mid-point or ―likely‖ estimate.<br />

An additional issue is the difference between the average <strong>and</strong> marginal per-mile cost <strong>of</strong> truck<br />

shipping. The marginal cost considers only the fuel savings. The average cost also considers any<br />

increase in the capital cost <strong>of</strong> the vehicle, amortized over the lifetime <strong>of</strong> the vehicle. For the<br />

purposes <strong>of</strong> this assessment it is assumed that vehicle owners will pass these capital costs along<br />

to their customers, <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e it is the average (net) cost or cost savings that is important.<br />

The rebound effect in heavy-duty vehicles works in three ways. The first two have been<br />

measured <strong>and</strong> characterized with price elasticities while the third is speculative:<br />

An increase in overall dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> truck shipping, if total shipping costs are reduced (the selfprice<br />

elasticity effect);<br />

A shift <strong>of</strong> some commodities from other modes (especially rail) to truck due to lower truck<br />

shipping costs (the cross-price elasticity effect); <strong>and</strong><br />

Less efficient utilization <strong>of</strong> trucks (e.g., lighter loads), because lower costs reduce cost<br />

pressures on industry to maximize efficiency.<br />

The self-price elasticity provides a measure <strong>for</strong> describing how the volume <strong>of</strong> truck shipping<br />

(dem<strong>and</strong>) changes with its price while the cross-price elasticity provides a measure <strong>for</strong> describing<br />

how the volume <strong>of</strong> rail shipping changes with truck price. In general, an elasticity describes the<br />

percent change in one variable (e.g. dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> trucking) in response to a percent-change in<br />

another (e.g. price <strong>of</strong> truck operations). For example, a price elasticity <strong>of</strong> truck dem<strong>and</strong> with<br />

respect to truck prices (self-price elasticity) <strong>of</strong> -0.5 implies that the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> trucking will grow<br />

by 5 percent if truck operations costs decrease by 10 percent (+5 percent change in truck<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>/-10 percent change in truck cost = -0.5). Similarly, a cross-price elasticity <strong>of</strong> rail dem<strong>and</strong><br />

with respect to truck prices (cross-price elasticity) <strong>of</strong> 0.5 implies that the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> rail will<br />

decrease by 5 percent if truck operations costs decrease by 10 percent (-5 percent change in rail<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>/-10 percent change in truck price = 0.5).<br />

2<br />

Oak Ridge National Laboratory, Transportation Energy Data Book, Edition 28, prepared <strong>for</strong> the US<br />

Department <strong>of</strong> Energy, 2009. See table 5.4 <strong>for</strong> relevant data.<br />

3<br />

Graham <strong>and</strong> Glaister, ―Road Traffic Dem<strong>and</strong> Elasticity Estimates: A Review,‖ Transport Reviews<br />

Volume 24, 3, pp. 261-274, 2004 <strong>and</strong> Oum, Waters, <strong>and</strong> Jong Say Yong, ―A Survey <strong>of</strong> Recent Estimates<br />

<strong>of</strong> Price Elasticities <strong>of</strong> Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> Transport,‖ prepared <strong>for</strong> the World Bank, Infrastructure <strong>and</strong> Urban<br />

Development Department, January 1990.<br />

- 5 -


Oum et al 4 collected 17 estimates <strong>of</strong> freight transportation dem<strong>and</strong> price elasticities. The authors<br />

focused on self-price elasticities <strong>and</strong> presented elasticity figures as both a range <strong>and</strong> a most likely<br />

estimate. The authors found that transportation is relatively inelastic since it is a derived dem<strong>and</strong><br />

– transportation dem<strong>and</strong> only exists because there is dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> other products or services –<br />

with the exception <strong>of</strong> freight shipments that are subject to intermodal rail competition. The paper<br />

found truck self-price elasticity to fall in the range <strong>of</strong> -0.05 to -1.34 with the most likely range <strong>of</strong><br />

-0.7 to -1.10 (the measures <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> were not identified <strong>and</strong> varied by study). 5 Furthermore,<br />

while the general literature on road transportation elasticities has distinguished short-run vs.<br />

long-run effects, this has not typically been done in the literature on truck elasticities.<br />

A more recent study by Christides <strong>and</strong> Leduc reviewed recent price elasticity literature <strong>for</strong> use in<br />

a truck size <strong>and</strong> weight study <strong>for</strong> the European Commission. 6 The literature review collected<br />

self-price elasticities ranging from -0.3 <strong>and</strong> -1.75 <strong>and</strong> cross-price elasticities ranging from 0.11 to<br />

1.9. For use in their study, they selected values <strong>of</strong> -0.416 <strong>for</strong> truck self-price elasticity, measured<br />

in tons, <strong>and</strong> 0.38 <strong>for</strong> rail cross-price elasticity, measured in tons.<br />

Graham <strong>and</strong> Glaister, 7 in a comprehensive review <strong>of</strong> recent price elasticity results, found that<br />

truck self-price elasticity is likely to fall between -0.5 <strong>and</strong> -1.5, but did not identify a dem<strong>and</strong><br />

measure. The Federal Highway Administration (FHWA) used a self-price elasticity <strong>of</strong> -0.97,<br />

measured in vehicle-miles, <strong>for</strong> a freight benefit <strong>and</strong> cost study. 8 A study <strong>for</strong> the National<br />

Cooperative Highway Research Program 9 cited a rail cross-price elasticity <strong>of</strong> 0.52 based on the<br />

Intermodal Competition Model 10 <strong>and</strong> identified a range <strong>of</strong> cross-price elasticities between 0.35<br />

<strong>and</strong> 0.59 from an analysis <strong>of</strong> Class 1 railroads. 11<br />

Approach: To estimate the potential rebound effects <strong>and</strong> resulting effects on fuel consumption it<br />

is necessary to describe a base case <strong>and</strong> to develop potential fuel economy improvement<br />

alternatives. It is necessary <strong>for</strong> the base case to describe current truck <strong>and</strong> rail volumes; truck <strong>and</strong><br />

rail fuel economy; truck <strong>and</strong> rail fuel consumption; average truck operating cost per-mile; <strong>and</strong><br />

truck purchase price. For alternatives, it is necessary to describe the potential fuel consumption<br />

4<br />

Oum, Waters, <strong>and</strong> Jong Say Yong, ―A Survey <strong>of</strong> Recent Estimates <strong>of</strong> Price Elasticities <strong>of</strong> Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

Transport,‖ prepared <strong>for</strong> the World Bank, Infrastructure <strong>and</strong> Urban Development Department, January<br />

1990.<br />

5<br />

While the authors find that dem<strong>and</strong> is ―relatively inelastic‖ this is not always the case, as an elasticity<br />

<strong>of</strong> 1.0 or -1.0 can be considered a dividing line between ―elastic‖ <strong>and</strong> ―inelastic,‖ with higher (absolute)<br />

values considered elastic.<br />

6<br />

Christidis <strong>and</strong> Leduc, ―Longer <strong>and</strong> Heavier Vehicles <strong>for</strong> freight transport,‖ European Commission Joint<br />

Research Center‘s Institute <strong>for</strong> Prospective Technology Studies, 2009.<br />

7<br />

Graham <strong>and</strong> Glaister, ―Road Traffic Dem<strong>and</strong> Elasticity Estimates: A Review,‖ Transport Reviews<br />

Volume 24, 3, pp. 261-274, 2004.<br />

8<br />

HDR-HLB Decision Economics, Inc. <strong>and</strong> ICF International, Freight Benefit/Cost Study: Phase III Analysis<br />

<strong>of</strong> Regional Benefits <strong>of</strong> Highway-Freight Improvements, prepared <strong>for</strong> the Federal Highway Administration<br />

Office <strong>of</strong> Freight Management <strong>and</strong> Operations, February 2008.<br />

9<br />

Cambridge Systematics, Inc., Characteristics <strong>and</strong> Changes in Freight Transportation Dem<strong>and</strong>: A Guidebook<br />

<strong>for</strong> Planners <strong>and</strong> Policy Analysts Phase II Report, National Cooperative Highway Research Program<br />

Project 8-30, June 1995.<br />

10<br />

Scott M. Dennis, The Intermodal Competition Model, Association <strong>of</strong> American Railroads, September 1988.<br />

11<br />

J. Jones, F. Nix, <strong>and</strong> C. Schwier, The Impact <strong>of</strong> Changes in Road User Charges on Canadian Railways,<br />

prepared <strong>for</strong> Transport Canada by the Canadian Institute <strong>of</strong> Guided Ground Transport, Kingston,<br />

Ontario, September 1990.<br />

- 6 -


eduction; logical fuel economy technologies to achieve the reduction; improved fuel economy;<br />

increased truck purchase price; resulting operating cost (including savings from fuel economy<br />

improvements <strong>and</strong> increased capital cost from increased purchase price); <strong>and</strong> self-price <strong>and</strong><br />

cross-price elasticities.<br />

Scenarios: Three scenarios are outlined below:<br />

Base case: Total affected truck volume is 142,706 million VMT <strong>and</strong> total affected rail volume is<br />

1,852 billion ton-miles; 12 truck fuel economy is 5.59 mpg 13 <strong>and</strong> average rail fuel economy is<br />

436 gallons per ton-mile; 14 truck fuel consumption is 25,500 million gallons <strong>and</strong> rail fuel<br />

consumption is 4,250 million gallons (based on estimates <strong>of</strong> travel <strong>and</strong> fuel economy); total<br />

truck operating costs are $1.73 per-mile ($247 billion nationally = $1.73/mile * 142,706 million<br />

miles), including $0.70 fuel-oil related costs (fuel costs <strong>and</strong> fuel tax costs) <strong>and</strong> $0.206 per-mile<br />

truck <strong>and</strong>/or trailer lease or purchase payments; 15 <strong>and</strong> the current purchase price <strong>of</strong> a Class 8<br />

tractor-trailer is $100,000. 16<br />

Alternative 1, 17.8 percent reduction in fuel use: In alternative 1, a set <strong>of</strong> technologies are<br />

implemented to achieve a 17.8 percent reduction in fuel consumption. The selection <strong>of</strong><br />

technologies <strong>and</strong> this target reduction were based on the <strong>for</strong>thcoming Northeast States Center<br />

<strong>for</strong> a Clean Air Future (NESCCAF) <strong>and</strong> International Council on Clean Transportation (ICCT)<br />

report 17 that outlines technologies, their impacts <strong>and</strong> their costs. The technologies include<br />

best-available aero-kit (fully aerodynamic mirrors, cab side extenders, integrated sleeper cab<br />

ro<strong>of</strong> fairings, aerodynamic bumper, full fuel tank fairings, side skirt fairings, <strong>and</strong> boat tails),<br />

wide single base tires, aluminum wheels, idle reduction, <strong>and</strong> improved lubricants. The<br />

technology improves fuel economy from 5.59 to 6.80 mpg at a cost <strong>of</strong> $22,930 per vehicle.<br />

Accounting <strong>for</strong> decreases in operating cost <strong>and</strong> increased capital cost, the net per-mile<br />

operating cost will be reduced to $1.65, $0.57 <strong>of</strong> which is fuel-oil related costs, down from<br />

$0.70 in the base case, <strong>and</strong> $0.25 <strong>of</strong> which is truck/trailer payments, up from $0.21 in the base<br />

case. The total national operating cost is $236 billion (142,706 vehicle-miles * $1.65/mile). The<br />

chosen range <strong>of</strong> self-price elasticity <strong>of</strong> truck dem<strong>and</strong> with respect to truck price is between -<br />

0.5 <strong>and</strong> -1.5 <strong>and</strong> the cross-price elasticity <strong>of</strong> rail dem<strong>and</strong> with respect to truck price is between<br />

0.35 <strong>and</strong> 0.59. These ranges were chosen to include the majority <strong>of</strong> the estimates while<br />

excluding the outliers.<br />

Alternative 2, 38.6 percent reduction in fuel use: In alternative 2, a set <strong>of</strong> technologies, again<br />

based on the ICCT report, are implemented to achieve a 38.6 percent reduction in fuel<br />

12<br />

Bureau <strong>of</strong> Transportation Statistics, Pocket Guide to Transportation, January 2009.<br />

13<br />

Energy In<strong>for</strong>mation Administration, ―Annual Energy Outlook, 2009,‖ March 2009.<br />

14<br />

Association <strong>of</strong> American Railroads, ―Freight Railroads <strong>and</strong> Greenhouse Gas Emissions,‖ June 2008.<br />

15<br />

American Transportation Research Institute, An Analysis <strong>of</strong> the Operational Costs <strong>of</strong> Trucking, December<br />

2008.<br />

16<br />

Anthony Grezler, ―US <strong>Heavy</strong> Duty Vehicle Fleets <strong>Technologies</strong> <strong>for</strong> Reducing CO 2 : An Industry<br />

Perspective,‖ Volvo Powertrain Corporation, August 23, 2007.<br />

17<br />

Northeast States Center <strong>for</strong> a Clean Air Future, Southeast Research Institute, TIAX, LLC., <strong>and</strong><br />

International Council on Clean Transportation, Reducing <strong>Heavy</strong>-Duty Long Haul Truck <strong>Fuel</strong> Consumption<br />

<strong>and</strong> CO 2 Emissions, September 2009.<br />

- 7 -


consumption. This set <strong>of</strong> technologies includes all alternative 1 technologies plus continued<br />

streamlining <strong>of</strong> the cab, a reshaped trailer, boat tail, full skirting <strong>of</strong> the cab <strong>and</strong> trailer, tractortrailer<br />

gap fairing, very low resistance tires, bottoming cycle, parallel hybrid system, <strong>and</strong> road<br />

speed governors set to 60 mph. The technology improves fuel economy from 5.59 to 9.10<br />

mpg at a cost <strong>of</strong> $71,630 per vehicle. Accounting <strong>for</strong> the reduced fuel cost <strong>and</strong> increased<br />

capital cost, the net per-mile operating cost will be reduced to $1.61, $0.43 <strong>of</strong> which are<br />

fuel-oil related costs, down from $0.70 in the base case, <strong>and</strong> $0.35 <strong>of</strong> which are truck <strong>and</strong><br />

trailer payments, up from $0.21 in the base case. The total national operating cost is $230<br />

billion (142,706 vehicle-miles * $1.61/mile). The elasticity ranges are the same as those<br />

employed in the alternative 1 analysis.<br />

Findings: The impact <strong>of</strong> the three potential rebound effects on the alternatives are described<br />

below:<br />

The first rebound effect – truck VMT increase<br />

Be<strong>for</strong>e accounting <strong>for</strong> the rebound effect, the fuel economy improvements <strong>of</strong> alternatives 1<br />

<strong>and</strong> 2 will reduce fuel consumption from 25,500 million gallons to 21,000 <strong>and</strong> 15,700 million<br />

gallons, respectively. This represents a reduction <strong>of</strong> 4,500 - 9,800 million gallons <strong>of</strong> fuel.<br />

Class 8 long-haul dem<strong>and</strong> will increase (rebound) by 3.2 - 9.5 billion VMT <strong>for</strong> alternative 1<br />

<strong>and</strong> 5.0 - 15.0 billion VMT <strong>for</strong> alternative 2, based on the projected net decrease in operating<br />

costs associated with fuel efficiency improvements <strong>of</strong> $0.08 <strong>and</strong> $0.12 cents per mile,<br />

respectively.<br />

The VMT increase will cause a rebound in fuel use. The rebound <strong>for</strong> alternative 1 will reduce<br />

the total fuel savings from 4,500 million gallons to 3,100 to 4,000 million gallons. Put another<br />

way, the rebound effect <strong>for</strong> Class 8 vehicle travel will range from 11 to 31 percent if the<br />

technologies in alternative 1 are implemented. The rebound <strong>for</strong> alternative 2 will reduce the<br />

total fuel savings from 9,800 million gallons to 8,200 to 9,300 million gallons, depending on<br />

the elasticity. This will cause a rebound ranging from 5 to 16 percent.<br />

The rebound effect varies depending on the elasticity <strong>and</strong> the cost-effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the<br />

technology. If the technology is more cost-effective, then there will be a larger rebound effect<br />

because the cost <strong>of</strong> trucking will come down to a larger degree, increasing the total growth in<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> trucking. Alternative 2 shows a lower rebound effect (on a percentage basis) than<br />

alternative 1 because alternative 1 deploys the most cost-effective technologies, with<br />

diminishing returns gained from the technologies deployed under alternative 2.<br />

The second rebound effect: diversion from rail<br />

Some <strong>of</strong> the increased truck travel will be diverted from rail. With truck per-mile operating<br />

costs dropping from $1.73 in the base case to $1.65 <strong>and</strong> $1.61 in alternatives 1 <strong>and</strong> 2, shippers<br />

will shift 28.7 to 48.4 billion ton-miles from rail carriers to truck carriers in alternative 1 <strong>and</strong><br />

45.4 to 76.5 billion ton-miles from rail shippers in alternative 2.<br />

The shift from rail to truck will reduce rail fuel consumption by 66 to 111 million gallons <strong>for</strong><br />

alternative 1 <strong>and</strong> 104 to 176 million gallons <strong>for</strong> alternative 2.<br />

Considering truck fuel savings, the truck rebound effect, <strong>and</strong> the rail fuel savings <strong>for</strong><br />

alternative 1 together, the fuel reductions <strong>of</strong> 4,500 million gallons will drop to 3,200 to 4,100<br />

- 8 -


million gallons, <strong>for</strong> a combined rebound effect <strong>of</strong> about 9 to 30 percent (compared to 11-31<br />

percent without rail fuel savings). Considering the same <strong>for</strong> alternative 2, the fuel reductions<br />

<strong>of</strong> 9,800 million gallons will drop to 8,300 to 9,500 million gallons, <strong>for</strong> a combined rebound<br />

effect <strong>of</strong> 3 to 15 percent (compared to 5-16 percent without rail fuel savings).<br />

The third rebound effect: utilization reduction<br />

Trucking is a cost-competitive business <strong>and</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its are historically razor-thin. While trucking<br />

companies work diligently to reduce operating costs out <strong>of</strong> competitive necessity, continued<br />

cost increases <strong>for</strong>ce fleet owners to continue to look <strong>for</strong> ways to reduce operating costs. The<br />

relief that comes from decreased operating cost (4 percent in alternative 1 <strong>and</strong> 7 percent in<br />

alternative 2) is not likely to create a significant change in utilization optimization. However,<br />

there is no evidence in the literature to quantify the degree to which trucking companies<br />

maximize the utilization <strong>of</strong> their equipment or to describe how this might change with total<br />

truck operating costs.<br />

(iii) Vehicle Class Shifting<br />

Key Question: If regulations or new technologies change the relative costs <strong>and</strong> per<strong>for</strong>mance<br />

characteristics <strong>of</strong> various classes <strong>of</strong> medium <strong>and</strong> heavy vehicles, will some buyers choose larger<br />

or smaller vehicles than they would have be<strong>for</strong>e the change<br />

Background: Past regulations have had an impact on the choice <strong>of</strong> vehicle characteristics. Prior to<br />

deregulation <strong>of</strong> the trucking industry, 4-axle trucks were common. After deregulation, most<br />

carriers shifted to 5-axle trucks since these trucks could carry more freight <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e operate<br />

more economically, given weight per axle restrictions.<br />

To induce class-shifting, truck fuel economy regulations would need to significantly increase the<br />

cost (or decrease the per<strong>for</strong>mance) <strong>of</strong> one class <strong>of</strong> truck relative to another. The specific nature <strong>of</strong><br />

a vehicle class-shifting effect will there<strong>for</strong>e depend upon how the regulations are structured. A<br />

―class-neutral‖ regulation could be conceived that does not lead to any shifts.<br />

There is little or no literature that describes the cross-class mode shift between truck types based<br />

on cost. The potential <strong>for</strong> class-shifting appears limited, however, because most equipment is<br />

chosen to fit the physical requirements <strong>of</strong> a particular shipment, not because <strong>of</strong> changes in fuel<br />

price. A shipper will hire carriers to minimize total logistics cost <strong>and</strong> the carrier will deliver a<br />

service at the minimum possible cost (to maximize their pr<strong>of</strong>its). The shipment could be longhaul<br />

(more than 500 miles, the one-day round-trip distance), short-haul (less than 500 miles), a<br />

drayage shipment between an intermodal facility <strong>and</strong> the final destination, or a local shipment<br />

between a regional warehouse <strong>and</strong> a grocery store. Shippers <strong>and</strong> carriers will give additional<br />

consideration to whether the commodity is high-value <strong>and</strong> time-sensitive or low-value <strong>and</strong> less<br />

time sensitive, whether the commodity will weigh-out or cube-out, <strong>and</strong> the labor cost. Other<br />

vocational medium- <strong>and</strong> heavy-duty truck owners have very specific carrying <strong>and</strong> sizing needs<br />

(e.g. dump trucks, garbage trucks, buses, <strong>and</strong> utility trucks). A shipper <strong>and</strong> carrier will examine<br />

the set <strong>of</strong> requirements, negotiate a rate, <strong>and</strong> choose the optimal truck <strong>for</strong> the shipment. Shifting<br />

between trucks <strong>and</strong> truck classes is complicated, but it is possible to conceive <strong>of</strong> some examples<br />

where certain policies would create cases where a truck from one class might become fungible<br />

with a truck from another class.<br />

- 9 -


Approach: Analysis first requires the identification <strong>of</strong> hypothetical regulations <strong>and</strong>, second, the<br />

identification <strong>of</strong> specific truck classes <strong>and</strong> shipment type that have potential <strong>for</strong> shifting given the<br />

regulations.<br />

Findings: The following is a sample <strong>of</strong> potential regulatory approaches <strong>and</strong> their possible<br />

impacts. The impacts are intended only to show the likely direction <strong>of</strong> shifting. A quantitative<br />

analysis would require a more specific underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> alternative regulations, the distribution<br />

<strong>of</strong> vehicle classes, the development <strong>of</strong> complete weight <strong>and</strong> operating cost tables <strong>for</strong> each vehicle<br />

type <strong>and</strong> class, <strong>and</strong> potentially, research with vehicle owners to determine how these impacts<br />

might affect their purchase decisions.<br />

Regulations that would increase or decrease the weight <strong>of</strong> a vehicle. If fuel economy regulations were to<br />

require all trucks to implement weight-increasing or –decreasing technologies, there are several<br />

potential outcomes, depending on the current use <strong>of</strong> the truck. Two potential outcomes are<br />

described below:<br />

Trucks used <strong>for</strong> certain types <strong>of</strong> specialized shipments that have similar trucks in different<br />

classes are the most likely to be interchangeable. For example, a FedEx delivery truck can be<br />

one <strong>of</strong> three classes, including Class 3, 4, or 5. 18 If regulations were to increase the weight <strong>of</strong> a<br />

Class 3 FedEx delivery truck <strong>and</strong> make it Class 4, FedEx might decide to simply purchase<br />

more Class 4 trucks going <strong>for</strong>ward. Other truck types that are fungible between Classes<br />

include city delivery (Classes 3, 4, <strong>and</strong> 5), conventional van (Classes 3 <strong>and</strong> 4), <strong>and</strong><br />

conventional tractors (Classes 7 <strong>and</strong> 8). In the long-run, these changes might result in larger<br />

(or smaller) trucks being used <strong>for</strong> deliveries <strong>of</strong> all sorts, which would lead to an increase in<br />

travel.<br />

Trucks used <strong>for</strong> certain types <strong>of</strong> specialized shipments that do not have similar trucks in<br />

different classes <strong>and</strong> are not likely to be interchangeable may still be impacted by a policy that<br />

would increase or decrease the gross vehicle weight. License requirements <strong>for</strong> Class 7<br />

vehicles make marginal Class 6 vehicles most likely to experience class-shift pressure from a<br />

regulation that would increase general gross vehicle weight. For example, if regulations were<br />

to require school buses to add a significant amount <strong>of</strong> weight, it is possible that they would<br />

become Class 7 vehicles. If that were to happen, school bus drivers would need to gain<br />

additional licensure or buses would need to counteract the weight gain <strong>and</strong> lose capacity.<br />

Other Class 6 vehicles that are marginal now (school bus, beverage trucks, rack trucks, <strong>and</strong><br />

single axle vans) might bump over to Class 7, which would require special driver licensure.<br />

Regulations that would be implemented based on geography <strong>of</strong> truck travel (e.g., requiring aero fairings on<br />

trucks traveling outside <strong>of</strong> the city):<br />

Some fuel-saving technologies are only cost-effective <strong>for</strong> certain types <strong>of</strong> uses. For example,<br />

aerodynamic improvements are most beneficial <strong>for</strong> high-speed, long-haul travel, while<br />

hybridized drivetrains are most beneficial <strong>for</strong> stop-<strong>and</strong>-go duty cycles. <strong>Fuel</strong> economy could<br />

be directly regulated depending upon the intended use <strong>of</strong> the vehicle, or technology<br />

requirements imposed based on intended use. Under the assumption that a regulation would<br />

18<br />

Cummins, ―<strong>Heavy</strong> Duty <strong>Fuel</strong> Efficiency Regulations,‖ July 2009.<br />

- 10 -


e defined as something similar to ‗percent <strong>of</strong> miles <strong>of</strong> travel on roads within Census Urban<br />

Area boundaries,‘ trucks that travel half in the city <strong>and</strong> half outside <strong>of</strong> the city represent a<br />

likely marginal case. Trucks meeting the marginal description are likely to be trucks that, <strong>for</strong><br />

example, carry goods between warehouses on the urban fringe <strong>and</strong> urban retailers. These<br />

carriers would likely make the argument that their travel was most <strong>of</strong>ten inside <strong>of</strong> the urbanarea<br />

boundary <strong>and</strong>, there<strong>for</strong>e, they should not be required to install fairings. They are not<br />

likely to shift classes to avoid regulation, as their shipments are not likely to change.<br />

Monitoring <strong>and</strong> en<strong>for</strong>cement <strong>of</strong> such a regulation would likely be a challenge, especially<br />

without the deployment <strong>of</strong> technologies such as global positioning systems (GPS) monitors as<br />

a basis <strong>for</strong> charging VMT fees. Additionally, urban area boundaries change after each<br />

decennial census, further reducing the practicality <strong>of</strong> this type <strong>of</strong> regulation.<br />

Regulations that impact a certain engine size:<br />

Regulations that would impact only a certain engine size would implicitly impact a certain<br />

class truck more than another. For example, if engine regulations were implemented on any<br />

engine with peak horsepower greater than 400, this would select <strong>for</strong> Class 8 trucks—either<br />

line-haul or other vocational loads. However, any regulations that would increase the<br />

operating cost <strong>for</strong> an engine sized <strong>for</strong> Class 8 use would be doing so <strong>for</strong> the class <strong>of</strong> trucks<br />

that are least likely to switch. Vocational trucks would still be used <strong>for</strong> job-specific purposes<br />

<strong>and</strong> other users <strong>of</strong> Class 8 trucks are extremely unlikely to shift to smaller trucks because<br />

labor costs would still far outweigh the increased operating cost that would accompany the<br />

required increase in shipments.<br />

For example, a steering column manufacturer in Vermont fills four 53-foot trailer-loads <strong>of</strong><br />

steering columns bound <strong>for</strong> an automobile manufacturing plant in Mississippi. If he were to<br />

shift this into a smaller Class 7 carrying a 28-foot pup trailer, it would take nearly twice as<br />

many truckloads, doubling the total number <strong>of</strong> shipments. The impact <strong>of</strong> switching to Class 7<br />

trucks will significantly increase total cost because fuel costs <strong>of</strong> Class 7 trucks are roughly 75<br />

percent <strong>of</strong> Class 8 fuel costs ($0.48 compared to $0.634 per mile) <strong>and</strong> labor is likely to remain<br />

similar since the shipment requirements are comparable. 19 Total labor costs will double (eight<br />

trucks compared to four) <strong>and</strong> fuel expense will increase by about 50 percent (eight trucks *<br />

$0.48 - four trucks * $0.634), resulting in a much more expensive shipment.<br />

(v) Transportation Service <strong>and</strong> Per<strong>for</strong>mance Effects<br />

Key Question: Are regulations likely to reduce the quality <strong>of</strong> the services provided by vehicles,<br />

<strong>for</strong> example by affecting speed, reliability, or cargo capacity If so, what are the implications <strong>for</strong><br />

costs <strong>and</strong> benefits<br />

Discussion: Initial research conducted by ERG <strong>for</strong> the concurrent white paper suggests that the<br />

impacts <strong>of</strong> fuel economy regulations on truck engine power output will be minimal, if any.<br />

There<strong>for</strong>e, the impacts <strong>of</strong> fuel economy regulations on quality <strong>of</strong> service are likely to be minimal<br />

19<br />

Antich, ―<strong>Medium</strong>-Duty Operating Costs Increase in 2008-CY,‖ reprinted from Work Truck Magazine,<br />

May/June 2009 <strong>and</strong> American Transportation Research Institute, An Analysis <strong>of</strong> the Operational Costs <strong>of</strong><br />

Trucking, December 2008.<br />

- 11 -


or non-existent. One exception is that some regulations may lead to the use <strong>of</strong> technologies that<br />

add modestly to the weight <strong>of</strong> the vehicle, which will modestly reduce cargo capacity on a weight<br />

basis. This will only be an issue <strong>for</strong> shipments that ―weigh out‖ (i.e., are limited by the maximum<br />

load allowed), <strong>and</strong> not those that ―cube out‖ (i.e., are limited by volume). It is also conceivable<br />

that some truck purchasers might purchase smaller engines due to the higher cost <strong>of</strong> meeting<br />

more stringent fuel economy st<strong>and</strong>ards. If this is the case, the purchaser has still determined that<br />

the reduced per<strong>for</strong>mance will not be a significant detriment to their ability to conduct business,<br />

<strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e, by definition, there is no significant impact to shippers or to the overall economy.<br />

(vi) Congestion Impacts<br />

Key Question: If regulations reduce truck per<strong>for</strong>mance <strong>and</strong>/or reduce or increase truck VMT,<br />

what are the potential implications <strong>for</strong> congestion<br />

Background: Section (ii) describes how the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> long-haul trucking could increase if fuel<br />

economy regulations effectively reduce the net operating cost <strong>of</strong> long-haul trucking. Truck<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> is estimated to increase by 3.2 to 15 billion VMT (an increase <strong>of</strong> 2.2 to 10.5 percent),<br />

depending on the technology alternative selected, the prevailing national truck price elasticity<br />

<strong>and</strong> rail cross price elasticity, regulation, <strong>and</strong> technology response. While degraded truck<br />

per<strong>for</strong>mance could also impact congestion, the concurrent white paper produced by ERG<br />

suggests that the impacts <strong>of</strong> fuel economy regulations on truck per<strong>for</strong>mance will be minimal, if<br />

any.<br />

The remainder <strong>of</strong> this analysis focuses on basic freeway sections because fuel economy<br />

regulations are most likely to affect long-haul truck traffic, which spend the vast majority <strong>of</strong> their<br />

time on freeways. (Trucks have a significant impact on congestion at other traffic control<br />

locations, such as signalized <strong>and</strong> unsignalized intersections, merge sections, <strong>and</strong><br />

freeway-to-freeway <strong>of</strong>f-ramps, but the data to analyze these impacts is not readily available.) In<br />

the highway capacity manual (HCM), in basic freeway analysis, trucks are represented as<br />

―passenger car equivalents‖ (PCE). 20 The PCE concept is meant to capture the effect that heavy<br />

vehicles have on traffic flow on a freeway because heavy vehicles occupy more space, travel more<br />

slowly up steep grades <strong>and</strong> more quickly down them, accelerate more slowly, brake more slowly,<br />

<strong>and</strong> change lanes more slowly than passenger cars. Furthermore, different passenger car<br />

operators react differently to the presence <strong>of</strong> trucks; <strong>for</strong> example, following further behind trucks<br />

than cars. An increase in the total truck traffic PCEs on the road could be attributable to a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> effects, most significantly an increase in total traffic, although there could also be<br />

modest impacts if trucks have lower power output, higher weight, or regulations that encourage<br />

class-shifting.<br />

The HCM increases the PCE <strong>for</strong> trucks based on roadway conditions such as grade, number <strong>of</strong><br />

lanes, distance to roadside obstructions, <strong>and</strong> width <strong>of</strong> lanes. It does not, however, distinguish<br />

between truck PCEs under congested <strong>and</strong> uncongested conditions. FHWA simulated the effect<br />

<strong>of</strong> combination trucks as part <strong>of</strong> its Truck Size <strong>and</strong> Weight Study to estimate how effective truck<br />

PCEs change based on the weight-to-horsepower ratio <strong>of</strong> the truck itself, the grade <strong>of</strong> the<br />

roadway, the road type, geography, <strong>and</strong> congestion levels. They did not estimate the impacts <strong>of</strong><br />

20<br />

Transportation Research Board, Highway Capacity Manual, Washington, D.C., 2000.<br />

- 12 -


other roadway characteristics such as lane width or distance to obstructions. 21 The tables from<br />

the FHWA report are reproduced in this paper <strong>and</strong> to show how different scenarios change how<br />

trucks impact roadway volumes. Generally, steeper grades, longer hills, fewer lanes, <strong>and</strong> a<br />

higher weight-to-horsepower ratio increase the number <strong>of</strong> PCEs <strong>for</strong> a single truck. Truck PCE<br />

conversions are necessary to calculate a volume-to-capacity (V/C) ratio, which can be used to<br />

estimate congestion <strong>and</strong> delay measurement. Figure A-1 at the end <strong>of</strong> this document shows PCEs<br />

<strong>for</strong> trucks on rural highways.<br />

While different <strong>for</strong>mulas have been developed to estimate traffic speeds based on V/C ratios, an<br />

illustrative example can be provided through the use <strong>of</strong> the Bureau <strong>of</strong> Public Roads (BPR)<br />

<strong>for</strong>mula:<br />

Congested Speed = (Free-Flow Speed) / (1 + 0.15 * [volume/capacity] ^ 4)<br />

The <strong>for</strong>mula implies that as a basic freeway segment approaches capacity (as the V/C ratio<br />

approaches 1.0), traffic speed will be reduced. To calculate delay, one must calculate both<br />

congested <strong>and</strong> free-flow travel time from the segment length <strong>and</strong> congested <strong>and</strong> free-flow speeds,<br />

then measure the difference between the free-flow travel time <strong>and</strong> the congested travel time.<br />

An alternative perspective on congestion measurement uses estimates from literature <strong>of</strong> the<br />

marginal cost <strong>of</strong> one combination truck on overall congestion. In one study, Parry estimates the<br />

marginal congestion cost <strong>of</strong> combination trucks to be $0.168 per mile in urban areas <strong>and</strong> $0.037<br />

per mile in rural areas. 22 The marginal congestion cost describes the cost, measured in lost travel<br />

time, that a single additional combination truck imposes on the rest <strong>of</strong> the traffic already on the<br />

roadway. Generally, as congestion increases, the marginal cost increases. In his analysis, Parry<br />

uses an estimate <strong>of</strong> PCEs that is consistent with the HCM but does not take into account the full<br />

impacts <strong>of</strong> trucks on congestion. To wit, the marginal cost estimates are likely to be larger.<br />

Approach:<br />

For estimation <strong>of</strong> change in delay: The approach taken is to conceptualize an average high-truck<br />

traffic basic freeway scenario, create a comparison scenario with additional 2.2 - 10.5 percent<br />

truck traffic (from Section (1)(ii)), estimate the V/C ratio <strong>for</strong> each scenario, estimate congested<br />

segment speeds based on the BPR <strong>for</strong>mula, <strong>and</strong> calculate delay <strong>for</strong> each scenario. This approach<br />

assumes that the average nationwide increase in truck traffic occurs on this hypothetical<br />

congested segment.<br />

For estimation <strong>of</strong> change in marginal cost: An alternative approach uses Parry‘s marginal congestion<br />

costs. To estimate total increased marginal congestion costs, the current urban <strong>and</strong> rural Class 8<br />

truck VMT is identified, <strong>and</strong> the percent change in VMT calculated in Section (1)(ii) applied to<br />

estimate the total marginal costs.<br />

21<br />

Battelle, ―Traffic Operations <strong>and</strong> Truck Size <strong>and</strong> Weight Regulations, Working Paper 6,‖ prepared <strong>for</strong><br />

the Federal Highway Administration, February 2005.<br />

22<br />

Parry, Ian, ―How Should <strong>Heavy</strong>-Duty Trucks Be Taxed‖ Resources <strong>for</strong> the Future, April 2006. See<br />

Table 1 <strong>for</strong> his benchmark parameter values <strong>for</strong> mileage-related marginal external costs.<br />

- 13 -


Scenarios <strong>for</strong> estimation <strong>of</strong> change in delay: A basic four-lane freeway segment (two lanes in either<br />

direction) is at capacity when there are at least 2,200 passenger cars per lane per hour, or 4,400<br />

passenger cars traveling in either direction. The roadway has a free-flow travel speed <strong>of</strong> 70 mph,<br />

no horizontal obstructions, two 12-foot travel lanes, no grade, <strong>and</strong> is 10 miles in length. The two<br />

scenarios below illustrate the impact <strong>of</strong> trucks on highway capacity under a condition <strong>of</strong><br />

moderately heavy dem<strong>and</strong>:<br />

Base scenario: A roadway that carries a significant number <strong>of</strong> trucks <strong>and</strong> passenger vehicles<br />

but currently operates at an acceptable level <strong>of</strong> service, <strong>and</strong> does not experience many hours<br />

<strong>of</strong> delay. The volume (dem<strong>and</strong>) consists <strong>of</strong> 3,400 total vehicles on the basic freeway segment<br />

per hour. Ten percent <strong>of</strong> them (340 vehicles) are trucks <strong>and</strong> they have, on average, a 500<br />

horsepower engine <strong>and</strong> a fully-loaded gross-vehicle weight <strong>of</strong> 80,000 lbs, which produces a<br />

weight to horsepower ratio <strong>of</strong> 160 lb/hp (80,000/500);<br />

Truck VMT increase scenario: This scenario is identical to the base scenario described above<br />

except that trucks are increased between 2.2 <strong>and</strong> 10.5 percent to grow with the increase in<br />

traffic described in Section (1)(ii).<br />

Findings:<br />

Base scenario <strong>for</strong> estimation <strong>of</strong> change in delay: To estimate the volume to capacity ratio, take the<br />

3,400 vehicles <strong>and</strong> add the additional PCEs created by the trucks. Each truck on this segment<br />

occupies the same capacity as 2.6 passenger vehicles (From Figure A-1, each truck is worth 2.6<br />

PCEs). The road operates as if there are 3,060 autos plus 884 PCEs (340*2.6), identical to a<br />

scenario where there are no trucks <strong>and</strong> 3,994 passenger cars. The estimated V/C ratio is<br />

3,944/4,400, or 0.90. Using the BPR <strong>for</strong>mula, the congested speed <strong>for</strong> this segment is 63.8 mph<br />

((70) / (1 + 0.15 * [3,944/4,400] ^ 4) =63.8 mph). It takes 8.6 minutes to travel the 10-mile<br />

roadway in free-flow conditions <strong>and</strong> 9.4 minutes in congested conditions, which implies a delay<br />

<strong>of</strong> 0.8 minutes per vehicle under the operating conditions described in the scenario. For all 3,400<br />

vehicles, this implies a total delay <strong>of</strong> 2,720 minutes <strong>of</strong> delay, approximately 45 hours.<br />

Truck VMT increase scenario <strong>for</strong> estimation <strong>of</strong> change in delay: In this scenario, truck volumes increase<br />

by 2.2 - 10.5 percent over the base scenario conditions, an increase <strong>of</strong> 8 - 36 trucks or an increase<br />

in total vehicles <strong>of</strong> 0.2 – 1.1 percent. The road now operates as though there are 3,060 autos plus<br />

904 - 978 PCEs (348*2.6; 376*2.6), identical to a scenario where there are no trucks <strong>and</strong><br />

3,964 - 4,038 passenger cars. The V/C ratio is 3,964/4,400 – 4,038/4,400, or 0.90 - 0.92. Using the<br />

BPR <strong>for</strong>mula, the congested speed <strong>for</strong> this segment is 63.7 - 63.3 mph. This marginally increases<br />

the travel time <strong>for</strong> the 10-mile segment to 9.4 - 9.5 minutes in congested conditions, which implies<br />

a delay <strong>of</strong> 0.8 - 0.9 minutes per vehicle. For all 3,408 - 3,436 vehicles, this implies a total delay <strong>of</strong><br />

2,726 - 3,092, approximately 45 - 52 hours – an increase in delay <strong>of</strong> 0 – 16 percent compared to the<br />

base scenario.<br />

This increase in delay is small compared to the overall travel time on this segment (although it is<br />

valid only at this particular point on the BPR curve.) Furthermore, the majority <strong>of</strong> VMT on U.S.<br />

freeways <strong>and</strong> arterial roadways occurs at acceptable levels <strong>of</strong> service (71 percent <strong>of</strong> urban VMT<br />

<strong>and</strong> 92 percent <strong>of</strong> rural VMT currently operates at level <strong>of</strong> service D or better) <strong>and</strong> impacts on<br />

these roadways are likely to be minimal. However, the marginal impact on delay will become<br />

larger as the capacity <strong>of</strong> the road is approached. For some roadways operating at or near<br />

- 14 -


capacity <strong>and</strong> with high truck volumes, it is possible that increased truck travel as a result <strong>of</strong> the<br />

rebound effect from higher fuel efficiency could have an impact on delay that is not insignificant.<br />

For estimation <strong>of</strong> change in marginal cost: The increase in rural <strong>and</strong> urban Class 8 truck VMT is 1.9 to<br />

8.7 billion VMT (58 percent <strong>of</strong> the previously estimated 3.2 to 15 billion VMT increase) <strong>and</strong> 1.3 to<br />

6.3 billion VMT (42 percent <strong>of</strong> the 3.2 to 15 billion VMT increase), respectively. 23 Using Parry‘s<br />

marginal congestion costs <strong>of</strong> $0.037 per-mile in rural areas <strong>and</strong> $0.168 per-mile in urban areas, the<br />

total increase in cost ranges from $0.3 billion to $1.4 billion (e.g. $0.3 billion = 1.9 billion rural<br />

VMT * $0.037 per-mile + 1.3 billion urban VMT * $0.168 per-mile).<br />

(vii) Safety Impacts<br />

Key Question: If regulations reduce truck per<strong>for</strong>mance <strong>and</strong>/or reduce or increase truck VMT,<br />

what are the potential implications <strong>for</strong> safety<br />

Background: Section (1)(ii) describes how the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> long-haul trucking will increase if fuel<br />

economy regulations effectively reduce long-haul truck operating costs. Truck traffic is estimated<br />

to increase between 3.2 <strong>and</strong> 15 billion VMT (an increase <strong>of</strong> 2.2 - 10.5 percent), depending on the<br />

technology alternatives <strong>and</strong> assumed dem<strong>and</strong> elasticities. Literature shows that truck traffic has<br />

a direct correlation with injuries <strong>and</strong> fatalities. Estimates <strong>of</strong> increased truck traffic can be<br />

multiplied by the injury <strong>and</strong> fatality crash rates to estimate the range <strong>of</strong> potential deaths <strong>and</strong><br />

injuries caused by the increase in travel.<br />

The concurrent white paper produced by ERG suggests that the impacts <strong>of</strong> fuel economy<br />

regulations on truck per<strong>for</strong>mance will be minimal, if any, <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e per<strong>for</strong>mance impacts on<br />

safety are not considered further.<br />

The safety impacts <strong>of</strong> changes in truck traffic can also be valued using marginal safety cost<br />

estimates from the literature. The marginal cost that one combination truck has on the safety <strong>of</strong><br />

the population describes the cost, measured in property damage, medical costs, value <strong>of</strong> a<br />

statistical life, etc. that a single additional combination truck imposes on the rest <strong>of</strong> the traffic<br />

already on the roadway. The marginal safety cost <strong>of</strong> combination trucks has been estimated by<br />

Parry to be $0.018 per mile in urban areas <strong>and</strong> $0.034 per mile in rural areas. 24 Generally, the<br />

marginal costs are higher in rural areas than in urban areas because the speeds are higher <strong>and</strong><br />

there is a higher likelihood <strong>of</strong> a larger speed differential, a key determining factor in highway<br />

accident severity <strong>and</strong> likelihood.<br />

Findings:<br />

For estimation <strong>of</strong> increase in injuries <strong>and</strong> fatalities: Recent data <strong>for</strong> highway crashes indicate crash<br />

rates <strong>for</strong> truck tractors with trailers <strong>of</strong> 2.4 per 100 million VMT <strong>for</strong> fatal crashes <strong>and</strong> 51.1 per 100<br />

23<br />

Federal Highway Administration, Highway Statistics, 2009 <strong>and</strong> Bureau <strong>of</strong> Transportation Statistics,<br />

Pocket Guide to Transportation, January 2009.<br />

24<br />

Parry, Ian, ―How Should <strong>Heavy</strong>-Duty Trucks Be Taxed‖, Resources <strong>for</strong> the Future, April 2006. See<br />

Table 1 <strong>for</strong> his benchmark parameter values <strong>for</strong> mileage-related marginal external costs.<br />

- 15 -


million VMT <strong>for</strong> injury crashes. 25 Based on these average rates, the rebound effect analysis<br />

(3.2 - 15 billion additional VMT annually) implies a national increase <strong>of</strong> 80 - 360 fatalities per year<br />

<strong>and</strong> 1,600 – 7,700 injuries per year.<br />

For estimation <strong>of</strong> change in marginal cost: The increase in rural <strong>and</strong> urban Class 8 truck VMT is 1.9 to<br />

8.7 billion VMT (58 percent <strong>of</strong> the previously estimated 3.2 to 15 billion VMT increase) <strong>and</strong> 1.3 to<br />

6.3 billion VMT (42 percent <strong>of</strong> the 3.2 to 15 billion VMT increase), respectively. 26 Using Parry‘s<br />

marginal congestion costs <strong>of</strong> $0.034 per-mile in rural areas <strong>and</strong> $0.018 per-mile in urban areas, the<br />

total increase in cost ranges from $0.09 billion to $0.4 billion (e.g. $0.09 billion = 1.9 billion rural<br />

VMT * $0.034 per-mile + 1.3 billion urban VMT * $0.018 per-mile)<br />

2. Alternative Approaches to Improving <strong>Fuel</strong> Efficiency<br />

Three alternative approaches to improving fuel efficiency are discussed in this section: a fuel tax,<br />

congestion pricing, <strong>and</strong> improvements in intermodal transport to divert freight from truck to rail.<br />

(i) <strong>Fuel</strong> Tax<br />

Key Question: What impact would an increase in the fuel tax (assessed on diesel fuel, all motor<br />

vehicle fuels, or an all fuels based on carbon content) have on truck fuel consumption<br />

Background: A fuel tax would affect truck fuel consumption in two ways: first, it would reduce<br />

truck traffic volumes, <strong>and</strong> second, it would encourage the purchase <strong>of</strong> more fuel-efficient vehicles<br />

<strong>and</strong> the retr<strong>of</strong>itting <strong>of</strong> existing vehicles with fuel-saving technology. It is possible to estimate the<br />

first effect, truck VMT reduction due to operating cost increase, using the elasticities <strong>of</strong> VMT with<br />

respect to price <strong>of</strong> truck travel as described in section (1)(ii).<br />

The second effect can similarly be evaluated using evidence on the elasticity <strong>of</strong> truck fuel<br />

efficiency with respect to fuel price. While there is considerable literature on this subject as<br />

applied to overall on-road vehicle traffic, this literature generally does not distinguish between<br />

personal <strong>and</strong> commercial vehicle elasticities <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e the primary effects represented are <strong>for</strong><br />

personal vehicles <strong>and</strong> travel. For example, Small <strong>and</strong> Van Dender (2007) provide a review <strong>of</strong><br />

previous studies as well as recent estimates using data through 2004. The authors estimate<br />

elasticities <strong>of</strong> VMT, fuel intensity (gallons/mile), <strong>and</strong> total fuel consumption (VMT multiplied by<br />

fuel intensity) with respect to fuel price changes. Elasticities are estimated both over a historical<br />

time period (1966 to 2004) <strong>and</strong> within the past few years (2000 to 2004) to examine how elasticities<br />

might be changing. These findings are shown in Table 1.<br />

25<br />

Federal Motor Carrier Safety Administration, ―Commercial Vehicle Facts,‖ November 2007<br />

http://www.fmcsa.dot.gov/facts-research/facts-figures/analysis-statistics/cmvfacts.htm<br />

(Accessed September 16, 2009).<br />

26<br />

Federal Highway Administration, Highway Statistics, 2009 <strong>and</strong> Bureau <strong>of</strong> Transportation Statistics,<br />

Pocket Guide to Transportation, January 2009.<br />

- 16 -


Table 1<br />

Historical <strong>and</strong> Recent Long-Run Elasticities With Respect to<br />

<strong>Fuel</strong> Price<br />

Calculated Long-Run Price Elasticities With<br />

Respect to <strong>Fuel</strong> Price <strong>of</strong>: Elasticity 1966 to 2004 Elasticity 2000 to 2004<br />

Vehicle Miles Traveled -0.210 -0.057<br />

<strong>Fuel</strong> Intensity -0.193 -0.191<br />

<strong>Fuel</strong> Consumption -0.363 -0.237<br />

Rebound Effect (Percentage) 21.0% 5.7%<br />

Source:<br />

Small <strong>and</strong> Van Dender (2007). The values shown in this table are “long-run” elasticities – i.e., response<br />

over a multi-year period after the price change. Long-run elasticities will be greater than the immediate<br />

or short-term response since travelers are able to make more fundamental adjustments to their<br />

activity patterns, such as changing residence or worksite locations or changing the number <strong>and</strong> types<br />

<strong>of</strong> vehicles owned.<br />

The findings imply, <strong>for</strong> example, that based on data from the 1966 to 2004 period, a 100 percent<br />

increase in fuel price should lead to a 21 percent reduction in VMT <strong>and</strong> a 19 percent increase in<br />

the fuel efficiency <strong>of</strong> vehicles, <strong>for</strong> an overall net decrease in fuel consumption <strong>of</strong> 36 percent. For<br />

the more recent period <strong>of</strong> 2000 to 2004, the elasticity <strong>of</strong> VMT with regard to fuel price declined<br />

substantially, such that a 100 percent increase in fuel price would lead to only a 6 percent long<br />

term decline in VMT. Table 1 shows that historically, about half <strong>of</strong> the impact <strong>of</strong> a fuel price<br />

increase would be on VMT reduction <strong>and</strong> the other half on fuel efficiency; but that in recent<br />

years, the VMT response to price increases has become much lower – less than one-third the<br />

magnitude <strong>of</strong> the fuel efficiency effect. Another recent review <strong>of</strong> elasticities by Sperling 27<br />

suggests that elasticity values are higher, but also reaches a similar conclusion that elasticities<br />

with respect to VMT have declined in recent years. Sperling found that long run elasticities <strong>of</strong><br />

fuel consumption with regard to fuel price “may be as low as -0.2.”<br />

Converting Small <strong>and</strong> van Dender‘s fuel intensity elasticity, which is measured in response to<br />

fuel prices, to an elasticity based on overall vehicle operating expenses, would imply about a two<br />

to three times higher elasticity (since fuel cost represents only about one-half to one-third <strong>of</strong> total<br />

operating costs, as discuss in Section (1)(ii)), or up to around two to three times -0.19 (about -0.4<br />

to -0.6). Doing the same with the 1966-2004 VMT elasticity produces a similar result, which falls<br />

at the lower end <strong>of</strong> the range identified previously through studies specific to truck traffic, <strong>and</strong><br />

about half the value selected above based on FHWA‘s report (-0.97).<br />

Approach:<br />

The question investigated here is what level <strong>of</strong> fuel tax would be required to reduce truck fuel<br />

consumption by roughly 20 to 40 percent, the same range <strong>of</strong> benefits assumed in the scenarios<br />

evaluated in Section (1)(ii). It is not known how well the elasticities reported by Small <strong>and</strong> Van<br />

Dender represent responses <strong>for</strong> the commercial vehicle sector. However, if it is assumed that the<br />

fuel intensity response is about the same magnitude as the VMT response, the previous analysis<br />

<strong>of</strong> VMT response can be used as a basis <strong>for</strong> estimating the combined response, by answering the<br />

question <strong>of</strong> what fuel price increase would be required to reduce VMT by 10 to 20 percent (<strong>and</strong><br />

27<br />

Sperling, Dan, ―Consumer Response to <strong>Fuel</strong> Price Changes: Implications <strong>for</strong> Policy,‖ January 15, 2008.<br />

- 17 -


assuming that a similar decrease in fuel intensity <strong>of</strong> 10 to 20 percent is also achieved, <strong>for</strong> a net<br />

effect in the range <strong>of</strong> 20 to 40 percent). The analysis is simplified by selecting an elasticity <strong>for</strong><br />

both rail <strong>and</strong> truck dem<strong>and</strong> used in relevant U.S. studies. The truck price elasticity <strong>of</strong> -0.97 used<br />

by FHWA <strong>and</strong> rail cross-elasticity <strong>of</strong> 0.52 from AAR were selected.<br />

Findings:<br />

The fuel tax necessary to achieve 20 - 40 percent lower fuel consumption in the average long-haul<br />

truck is $0.18 - $0.36 per mile. Because the cost <strong>of</strong> fuel per mile is currently $0.634 28 at an average<br />

fuel economy <strong>of</strong> 5.59 mpg, the data imply a fuel price <strong>of</strong> $3.54 gallon ($0.634 per mile * 5.59 miles<br />

per gallon). Using the same conversion, the increase in the per-mile fuel tax translates to an<br />

increase in the per-gallon fuel tax <strong>of</strong> $1.01 - $1.98, <strong>for</strong> the 20 <strong>and</strong> 40 percent scenarios<br />

respectively. This will reduce truck fuel consumption by 5,100 - 10,100 million gallons (20 - 40<br />

percent from current fuel consumption levels <strong>of</strong> 25,500 million gallons).<br />

This corresponds to a decrease in truck traffic from current annual VMT <strong>of</strong> 71,400 to 67,000 or<br />

43,000 <strong>for</strong> the 20 <strong>and</strong> 40 percent reduction cases, respectively. Based on the cross-price elasticity<br />

<strong>of</strong> 0.52, rail ton-miles will increase from 1,852 billion ton-miles to 1,953 - 2,053 billion ton miles in<br />

the 20 - 40 percent cases. This increase in rail traffic will increase rail fuel consumption by<br />

230 - 460 million gallons. This will reduce the impact <strong>of</strong> the truck fuel tax increase from<br />

5,100 - 10,100 to 4,870 - 9,640 million gallons, reducing the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the reduction by<br />

approximately 5 percent in both cases.<br />

Potential <strong>for</strong> Government Promotion: An increase in the Federal diesel motor fuel tax would be<br />

easy to administer as the mechanism already exists <strong>for</strong> levying <strong>and</strong> collecting this tax. However,<br />

the increase required to achieve significant fuel efficiency benefits – estimated to be in the range<br />

<strong>of</strong> $1 to $2 per gallon – is much higher than would be acceptable in the current policy<br />

environment (where, in fact, even small increases <strong>of</strong> five to 10 cents per gallon may be considered<br />

intolerable). It also significantly exceeds the likely fuel price increase under a national<br />

cap-<strong>and</strong>-trade program. Analysis by the Energy In<strong>for</strong>mation Administration (EIA) <strong>of</strong> cap <strong>and</strong><br />

trade legislation under the previous Congress showed that a $50 per tonne allowance price – at<br />

the upper range <strong>of</strong> what would be expected in 2030 – corresponds to a gasoline price increase <strong>of</strong><br />

about 45 cents per gallon in 2030. 29 A lower allowance price <strong>of</strong> $30 per tonne (27 cents per gallon)<br />

is consistent with the range in the draft American Clean Energy <strong>and</strong> Security Act <strong>of</strong> 2009. Using<br />

the same assumptions as the above analysis, this price would result in a decrease in commercial<br />

vehicle fuel consumption <strong>of</strong> only about 5 percent.<br />

(ii) Congestion Pricing<br />

Key Question: What impact would congestion pricing have on fuel consumption<br />

Background: Congestion pricing could take different <strong>for</strong>ms, such as area-wide network pricing<br />

on freeways <strong>and</strong> possibly arterials, ―cordon‖ or area pricing in central business districts, or<br />

28<br />

American Transportation Research Institute, An Analysis <strong>of</strong> the Operational Costs <strong>of</strong> Trucking, December<br />

2008.<br />

29<br />

U.S. Department <strong>of</strong> Energy, Energy In<strong>for</strong>mation Administration, ―Energy Market <strong>and</strong> Economic<br />

Impacts <strong>of</strong> S. 2191, the Lieberman-Warner Climate Security Act <strong>of</strong> 2007,‖ 2008.<br />

http://www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/service_rpts.htm<br />

- 18 -


truck-specific congestion pricing such as the varying time-<strong>of</strong>-day gate fees implemented at the<br />

Ports <strong>of</strong> Los Angeles <strong>and</strong> Long Beach.<br />

Congestion pricing could affect truck fuel consumption by:<br />

Shifting trips to less-congested <strong>of</strong>f-peak hours;<br />

Reducing congestion <strong>for</strong> trucks continuing to operate during peak periods;<br />

Reducing overall goods movement <strong>and</strong> related truck traffic due to higher costs; <strong>and</strong><br />

Shifting logistics patterns – e.g., leading industries to establish consolidation centers on the<br />

edges <strong>of</strong> urban areas to reduce truck activity within the congested area.<br />

Area-wide congestion pricing is applicable to freeways <strong>and</strong> major arterials where there is<br />

significant congestion. Cordon pricing strategies are only applicable in major urban areas with<br />

significant congestion. The limited geographic applicability <strong>of</strong> these two scenarios limits the fuel<br />

reduction potential. Area-wide congestion pricing has greater potential since it is estimated that<br />

nearly 30 percent <strong>of</strong> urban VMT occurs at level <strong>of</strong> service E or F. Cordon pricing <strong>of</strong> metropolitan<br />

area central business districts, however, is estimated to affect only 3 percent <strong>of</strong> total VMT<br />

nationwide. Furthermore, evidence suggests that there will be little, if any, overall impact on<br />

total truck traffic (as the added costs are likely to be marginal, or the option <strong>of</strong> moving to the<br />

<strong>of</strong>f-peak period acceptable), but rather that the benefits will occur from trucks operating under<br />

improved flow conditions, <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e using less fuel due to idling or stop-<strong>and</strong>-go operations.<br />

This will have a larger impact on smaller urban trucks since larger long distance trucks operate<br />

mostly on uncongested highways.<br />

It should be noted that while reducing congestion should improve fuel economy up to a point<br />

(e.g., increasing average speeds from 10 to 20 or 20 to 30 mph), truck fuel consumption rates also<br />

tend to increase at higher speeds (over 45-55 mph), <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e, increasing speeds from<br />

mid-range congestion (30-40 mph) to free-flow highway speeds may have a negative fuel<br />

economy impact. Congestion is likely to affect urban service <strong>and</strong> delivery movements more than<br />

long-haul freight, <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e it is the fuel consumption characteristics <strong>of</strong> smaller trucks that<br />

are most important.<br />

If congestion pricing is implemented only on a limited basis (e.g., only freeways), diversion <strong>of</strong><br />

traffic to other nontolled facilities is likely to be a significant concern because <strong>of</strong> the impacts on<br />

neighborhood <strong>and</strong> local traffic. Increases in VMT on alternate routes could <strong>of</strong>fset the fuel savings<br />

achieved from reductions in VMT <strong>and</strong> congestion on the facility itself. There<strong>for</strong>e, congestion<br />

pricing will be most effective at reducing fuel consumption if it is implemented universally (on<br />

all major roads in an area).<br />

While reducing congestion can save fuel, there is an implicit limit on these savings, bounded by<br />

the total fuel wasted in existing congestion. In this analysis, a sketch-level estimate is made <strong>of</strong> the<br />

total fuel ―wasted‖ by trucks, <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e the potential upper bound benefits <strong>of</strong> congestion<br />

relief strategies. This analysis only considers the fuel savings from improved traffic operations,<br />

<strong>and</strong> not any reduction in fuel use due to an overall decrease in dem<strong>and</strong>.<br />

Findings: Most studies <strong>of</strong> the impact <strong>of</strong> congestion pricing have focused on all traffic, rather than<br />

distinguishing impacts on personal vs. commercial vehicle traffic. A study <strong>for</strong> the U.S.<br />

- 19 -


Department <strong>of</strong> Energy used travel dem<strong>and</strong> models in Minneapolis-St. Paul <strong>and</strong> Seattle, in<br />

conjunction with speed-fuel efficiency relationships, to evaluate the combined benefits <strong>of</strong> travel<br />

reductions <strong>and</strong> operating efficiencies from areawide systems <strong>of</strong> managed lanes. 30 The results<br />

from different scenarios ranged from an 0.1 to 2.5 percent impact on fuel consumption <strong>and</strong> GHG<br />

emissions depending upon the scenario. Extrapolating these results to a national level based on<br />

projected 2030 congestion levels in different urbanized areas led to an overall estimated reduction<br />

in national fuel consumption ranging from 0.5 to 1.1 percent. 31 Another national study <strong>of</strong><br />

greenhouse gas (GHG) emission reduction strategies estimated that cordon pricing could<br />

potentially reduce VMT on the order <strong>of</strong> 3 percent if applied to all metropolitan areas in the<br />

United States. 32 These are rough estimates <strong>for</strong> all vehicles, however, that may not be transferable<br />

to truck traffic.<br />

Evaluations <strong>of</strong> cordon pricing schemes implemented in both London <strong>and</strong> Stockholm examined<br />

effects specifically on truck traffic. Experience in London suggests that the reduction in overall<br />

vehicle-kilometers <strong>of</strong> travel (VKT) has come almost exclusively from passenger vehicles rather<br />

than trucks. While the cordon pricing scheme reduced total VKT by 16 percent within the pricing<br />

zone, the data show that truck dem<strong>and</strong> did not change once the scheme was introduced,<br />

remaining at a constant level <strong>of</strong> 0.07 million VKT in 2006. Truck travel speeds also did not<br />

change significantly. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, truck trips crossing the cordon declined, suggesting that<br />

each truck makes more deliveries, generating an equivalent truck VKT. Furthermore, these<br />

trucks have benefited from reduced queuing <strong>and</strong> subsequently, truck idling <strong>and</strong> associated fuel<br />

consumption was reduced.<br />

To measure the impact <strong>of</strong> London‘s cordon pricing scheme on truck fuel consumption, it is<br />

necessary to compare truck idling be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>and</strong> after the scheme was introduced. Once the scheme<br />

was introduced, excess delays were reduced by 26 percent, from 2.3 to 1.7 minutes per<br />

kilometer. 33 Given 70,000 truck-kilometers traveled <strong>and</strong> a reduction in excess idling delay <strong>of</strong> 0.6<br />

minutes per kilometer (2.3-1.7 minutes per kilometer), the scheme reduced truck idling by a total<br />

<strong>of</strong> 42,000 minutes (700 hours). With each truck hour <strong>of</strong> idling consuming 0.8 gallons per hour, 34<br />

the truck fuel consumption reduction from congestion pricing would have been 560 gallons<br />

annually – a very small amount.<br />

30<br />

These systems included high-occupancy/toll (HOT) lanes on freeways, in which drivers <strong>of</strong> singleoccupancy<br />

vehicles can use the lane if they pay a fee which depends upon the congestion on the<br />

untolled travel lanes. Depending upon the scenario, either existing/planned high-occupancy vehicle<br />

(HOV) lanes were converted to HOT lanes, or a new HOT lane was constructed alongside an<br />

existing/planned HOV lane to <strong>for</strong>m two HOT lanes.<br />

31<br />

Energy <strong>and</strong> Environmental Analysis, Inc., ―Market-Based Approaches to <strong>Fuel</strong> <strong>Economy</strong>: Summary <strong>of</strong><br />

Policy Options,‖ prepared <strong>for</strong> National Energy Technology Laboratory, U.S. Department <strong>of</strong> Energy,<br />

2008.<br />

32<br />

Cambridge Systematics, Inc., Moving Cooler: An Analysis <strong>of</strong> Transportation Strategies <strong>for</strong> Reducing<br />

Greenhouse Gas Emissions, Urban L<strong>and</strong> Institute: Washington, D.C, July 2009.<br />

33<br />

Transport <strong>for</strong> London, Central London Congestion Charging: Impacts Monitoring, Fourth Annual Report, June<br />

2006.<br />

34<br />

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, ―A Glance at Clean Freight Strategies: Idle Reduction,‖<br />

February, 2004.<br />

- 20 -


In Stockholm, the cordon pricing scheme reduced total GHG emissions from vehicles by 10 to 14<br />

percent in the pricing zone. According to the manual counts <strong>of</strong> travel within the zone, there has<br />

been a 13 percent reduction <strong>of</strong> truck trips, but only a 7.8 percent reduction in truck VMT once the<br />

scheme was implemented. The total VMT is 2,185,000 <strong>and</strong> heavy truck VMT is 55,994, 2.8 percent<br />

<strong>of</strong> total VMT. If the GHG were reduced by 14 percent, then trucks were responsible <strong>for</strong> 0.4<br />

percent <strong>of</strong> the total reductions, a modest amount.<br />

To estimate the maximum potential fuel savings from congestion reduction, it is necessary to<br />

estimate total freight truck delay as well as total fuel consumption by hour <strong>of</strong> delay. Winston <strong>and</strong><br />

Langer 35 estimate the cost <strong>of</strong> congestion to freight trucks to be approximately $10 billion in the<br />

year 2000, based on the Texas Transportation Institute‘s measures <strong>of</strong> urban delay in 2000 <strong>and</strong> the<br />

FHWA Freight Analysis Framework estimates <strong>of</strong> total origin-destination delay. Using the<br />

authors‘ value <strong>of</strong> time <strong>of</strong> $30 per hour <strong>of</strong> delay, the results imply a total <strong>of</strong> 333 million hours <strong>of</strong><br />

delay ($10 billion/$30 per hour). According to a 1993 FHWA study, which produced fuel<br />

consumption estimates <strong>for</strong> the Highway Per<strong>for</strong>mance Monitoring System, a combination truck<br />

consumes 1.934 gallons <strong>of</strong> fuel per hour in congestion. 36 These values imply that, in 2000, the<br />

total excess national fuel consumption resulting from highway congestion was at most 500<br />

million gallons (333 million hours * 1.51 gallons/hour), or 2.0 percent <strong>of</strong> (current) truck fuel<br />

consumption. 37 This value provides the upper bound <strong>for</strong> the potential fuel consumption savings<br />

from congestion reduction strategies (including congestion pricing), assuming that only<br />

operational (<strong>and</strong> not dem<strong>and</strong>) effects are considered.<br />

Potential <strong>for</strong> Government Promotion: Congestion pricing has been experimented with in a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> areas, primarily on existing tolled facilities, but has not yet gained widespread<br />

popularity. From a technical st<strong>and</strong>point, congestion pricing is relatively easy to implement on<br />

facilities that already are tolled. The broader-scale application <strong>of</strong> this strategy beyond existing or<br />

proposed toll highway facilities, however, is likely to require the universal deployment <strong>of</strong><br />

electronic toll collection technologies. This will require coordination by a state or regional<br />

transportation agency. The U.S. DOT is encouraging greater experimentation in this area. In<br />

2007, the Department awarded $853 million in funding to five metro areas <strong>for</strong> Urban Partnership<br />

Agreements to reduce congestion, which include a significant focus on tolling/pricing strategies.<br />

(iii) Intermodal Transport<br />

Key Question: What impact would public-sector initiatives to improve intermodal transport<br />

have on fuel consumption<br />

35<br />

Winston <strong>and</strong> Langer, ―The Effect <strong>of</strong> Government Highway Spending on Road Users‘ Congestion<br />

Costs,‖ AEI-Brookings, May 2006.<br />

36<br />

Science Applications International Corporation, Speed Determination Models <strong>for</strong> the Highway Per<strong>for</strong>mance<br />

Monitoring System, prepared <strong>for</strong> the Federal Highway Administration, 1993.<br />

37<br />

Two factors may cause this estimate to be overstated – first, the use <strong>of</strong> the combination truck fuel<br />

consumption rate slightly overestimates the total wasted fuel since this rate will be less <strong>for</strong> single-unit<br />

trucks (1.607 gallons/hr); <strong>and</strong> second, trucks have become more fuel-efficient since that time (average<br />

truck fuel efficiency increased by 22 percent between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 2007, according to the Transportation Energy<br />

Data Book Edition 28, Table 5.1). On the other h<strong>and</strong>, total congestion has increased since the Winston <strong>and</strong><br />

Langer study was conducted in 2000.<br />

- 21 -


Background: Improvements to intermodal transport, such as rail capacity improvements <strong>and</strong><br />

bottleneck relief, intermodal (truck-rail) terminals, <strong>and</strong> financial/pricing incentives, could<br />

potentially encourage shippers to make greater use <strong>of</strong> rail in place <strong>of</strong> truck, increasing the<br />

efficiency <strong>of</strong> freight movement on a ton-mile basis.<br />

Work in progress <strong>for</strong> U.S. DOT on transportation GHG reduction strategies includes a literature<br />

review <strong>of</strong> the potential GHG benefits <strong>of</strong> shifting freight from truck to rail through intermodal<br />

improvements. 38 Reductions in fuel consumption on the order <strong>of</strong> 60 percent per ton-mile are<br />

typical <strong>for</strong> shifts from trucking (trailers or containers) to long-haul intermodal rail, with<br />

reductions decreasing with shorter distances. Savings can vary significantly, however,<br />

depending upon the distance <strong>of</strong> the movement <strong>and</strong> type <strong>of</strong> cargo.<br />

Estimates <strong>of</strong> total potential freight mode-shifting have been aspirational in nature, rather than<br />

based on empirical data, due in large part to the complex nature <strong>of</strong> competition between trucks<br />

<strong>and</strong> rail. The potential <strong>for</strong> mode-shifting is limited to certain types <strong>of</strong> commodities—those that<br />

are heavy, low-value, <strong>and</strong> do not have an acute need <strong>for</strong> reliable <strong>and</strong> timely delivery—e.g.,<br />

building stone <strong>and</strong> waste, as well as certain movements—in particular, long-haul movements<br />

where the efficiency benefits <strong>of</strong> rail outweigh the additional h<strong>and</strong>ling/logistics costs <strong>and</strong> time at<br />

either end, generally shipments longer than 1,000 miles. Furthermore, market dem<strong>and</strong> both<br />

affects <strong>and</strong> is dependent upon the quality <strong>of</strong> service. Rail service improves significantly as<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> between market pairs increases – increased traffic (trains per day) increases the level <strong>of</strong><br />

service that railroads provide to customers, <strong>and</strong> means that improved access is possible since<br />

(shippers need access to rail facilities to ship via rail). In short, shippers choose a mode that<br />

minimizes their total logistics cost.<br />

There are numerous ways to estimate diversion, but each has its flaws. In general, simple<br />

techniques (e.g., the ‗Delphi Method,‘ comparative market analysis, <strong>and</strong> elasticity methods) rely<br />

on simplifying assumptions <strong>and</strong> sketch planning techniques while complicated techniques (such<br />

as FHWA <strong>and</strong> the Federal Railroad Administration‘s Intermodal Transportation <strong>and</strong> Inventory<br />

Cost Model 39 <strong>and</strong> econometric models) require significant data resources, time resources, <strong>and</strong><br />

computation power. Furthermore, complicated techniques are very sensitive to inputs <strong>and</strong> the<br />

inputs are <strong>of</strong>ten modeled. For example, public truck flow data, by commodity, do not exist while<br />

rail data is sampled, proprietary, <strong>and</strong> requires traffic modeling <strong>for</strong> model estimation, all <strong>of</strong> which<br />

decrease the reliability <strong>of</strong> results.<br />

Despite the difficulties <strong>of</strong> estimating the size <strong>of</strong> diversion impacts, it is generally accepted that<br />

this phenomenon exists <strong>and</strong> that there are a consistent set <strong>of</strong> variables that impact the outcome.<br />

Actions that can affect a truck-rail mode shift include investment in rail <strong>and</strong> intermodal terminal<br />

infrastructure, direct operating subsidies <strong>for</strong> railroads, l<strong>and</strong> use regulations (<strong>for</strong> example, to<br />

preserve rail sidings <strong>for</strong> rail-oriented businesses), <strong>and</strong> taxes to increase the cost <strong>of</strong> truck travel, as<br />

previously discussed.<br />

38<br />

Cambridge Systematics, Inc., Transportation’s Role in Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions, Forthcoming,<br />

prepared <strong>for</strong> Federal Highway Administration.<br />

39<br />

Federal Highway Administration <strong>and</strong> Federal Railroad Administration, Intermodal Transportation <strong>and</strong><br />

Inventory Cost Model, Highway-to-Rail Intermodal User’s Manual, March 2005.<br />

- 22 -


Findings: The following studies either estimated diversion potential from rail investment in<br />

specific corridors.<br />

Mid-Atlantic Rail Operations (MAROps) study: 40 The MAROps study used the comparative<br />

market approach to estimate the diversion potential in the Mid-Atlantic region. The<br />

comparative market approach looked at every market pair in the country <strong>and</strong> compared rail<br />

travel distance to truck travel distance (a measure <strong>of</strong> the circuity <strong>of</strong> rail), commodity, traffic<br />

density (tons <strong>of</strong> good shipped), <strong>and</strong>, finally, mode-share <strong>of</strong> truck <strong>and</strong> rail. Mid-Atlantic<br />

markets were identified that, given similar operating conditions to other markets nationally,<br />

could carry more rail traffic, which would reduce truck traffic on the parallel highway<br />

corridor. The study estimated the potential diversion from projects representing a $12 billion<br />

investment in the Mid-Atlantic rail network to be somewhere between 0.67 <strong>and</strong> 1.8 million<br />

truck trips annually, or 237 to 638 million VMT (4 to 11 percent <strong>of</strong> total regional truck VMT)<br />

in 2035 (unpublished result). This diversion would save 42 to 114 million gallons <strong>of</strong> diesel<br />

fuel in trucks (based on today‘s 5.59 mpg fuel economy), not accounting <strong>for</strong> increased rail<br />

traffic. This implies a range <strong>of</strong> $7,000 to $18,000 per diverted truck trip in the Mid-Atlantic<br />

<strong>and</strong> between $110 <strong>and</strong> $290 in investment per gallon <strong>of</strong> fuel saved based on 2008 dollars <strong>and</strong><br />

2035 traffic.<br />

Norfolk Southern Crescent Corridor: 41 The Crescent Corridor will provide premium service<br />

intermodal trains to compete with I-81 long-haul truck markets between the New York area<br />

<strong>and</strong> the Southeast. This market is underserved by rail today <strong>and</strong> has significant potential <strong>for</strong><br />

growth. Improvements include new track, upgrading signals, <strong>and</strong> removing choke points.<br />

Norfolk Southern estimates that a $2.5 billion investment will result in the diversion <strong>of</strong><br />

1,000,000 truck trips annually. Over an assumed 30 year life <strong>of</strong> the project, this implies a cost<br />

<strong>of</strong> $83 per truck trip ($2.5 billion / (1 million trips * 30 years), <strong>and</strong> a savings <strong>of</strong> more than 170<br />

million gallons annually.<br />

The Northeast-Southeast-Midwest Corridor Marketing Study: 42 This study used the Reebie<br />

Associates‘ Diversion Model, a detailed statistical model, to estimate diversion from truck to<br />

rail based on reductions in rail operating costs stimulated by public investment in rail<br />

infrastructure. The study found that a long-term (13 to 17 years), corridor-wide (the entire I-<br />

81 corridor), public investment in rail intermodal infrastructure <strong>of</strong> $7.9 billion could divert<br />

approximately 812 million truck VMT. The study did not estimate the probable reduction in<br />

fuel consumption but the findings imply that truck fuel consumption would be reduced by<br />

145 million gallons annually (812 million VMT/5.59 mpg), implying $54 in investment costs<br />

per gallon <strong>of</strong> fuel saved in 2003 dollars.<br />

40<br />

Cambridge Systematics, Inc., Mid-Atlantic Rail Operations Study, prepared <strong>for</strong> the I-95 Corridor<br />

Coalition, <strong>for</strong>thcoming.<br />

41<br />

http://www.nscorp.com/nscportal/nscorp/Media/News%20Releases/2009/greencastle.html<br />

(Accessed September 16, 2009)<br />

42<br />

Reebie Associates, The Northeast-Southeast-Midwest Corridor Marketing Study, prepared <strong>for</strong> Virginia<br />

Department <strong>of</strong> Rail <strong>and</strong> Public Transportation, December 2003.<br />

- 23 -


Potential <strong>for</strong> Government Promotion: The government could promote rail diversion through the<br />

promotion <strong>of</strong> freight villages; aiding in the siting <strong>of</strong> intermodal terminals, transload facilities, <strong>and</strong><br />

bulk storage facilities; exp<strong>and</strong> market reach <strong>for</strong> regional railroads; <strong>and</strong> the continued<br />

improvement in rail infrastructure, including signal, track, bridge, terminal, <strong>and</strong> clearance<br />

upgrades.<br />

While freight rail infrastructure investment has traditionally been left to the private sector, the<br />

Federal government as well as a number <strong>of</strong> states have increasingly become involved in this issue<br />

<strong>for</strong> purposes <strong>of</strong> economic development <strong>and</strong> road traffic reduction. There are several state <strong>and</strong><br />

Federal programs that will fund rail improvement to help bridge the gap between investment<br />

needs <strong>and</strong> the availability <strong>of</strong> private capital. The Federal-aid highway funding program also<br />

allows some flexibility in using funds <strong>for</strong> non-highway freight transportation projects.<br />

To date most <strong>of</strong> the easier rail capacity improvement projects have been built, leaving primarily<br />

the more difficult <strong>and</strong> expensive projects. In addition to being expensive, many <strong>of</strong> the remaining<br />

critical needs are set in urban environments where there are substantial constraints on<br />

right-<strong>of</strong>-way as well as added costs <strong>for</strong> mitigation <strong>of</strong> impacts. These barriers will pose challenges<br />

to large-scale improvements in freight infrastructure sufficient to leverage significant truck-rail<br />

mode shift.<br />

- 24 -


Figure A-1 Vehicle Passenger Car Equivalents on Rural Highways<br />

Source: Battelle, ―Traffic Operations <strong>and</strong> Truck Size <strong>and</strong> Weight Regulations, Working Paper 6,‖<br />

prepared <strong>for</strong> the Federal Highway Administration, February 2005.<br />

- 25 -

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!