06.05.2015 Views

The Role of Source- and Host-Country Characteristics in ... - CReAM

The Role of Source- and Host-Country Characteristics in ... - CReAM

The Role of Source- and Host-Country Characteristics in ... - CReAM

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Role</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Source</strong>- <strong>and</strong> <strong>Host</strong>-<strong>Country</strong><br />

<strong>Characteristics</strong> <strong>in</strong> Female Immigrant Labor<br />

Supply ∗<br />

Julia Bredtmann a,b <strong>and</strong> Sebastian Otten a,b<br />

a Ruhr University Bochum<br />

b RWI Essen<br />

Very prelim<strong>in</strong>ary version<br />

Please do not quote!<br />

Abstract<br />

Us<strong>in</strong>g data from the European Social Survey 2002-2010, cover<strong>in</strong>g immigrants <strong>in</strong><br />

24 European countries, this paper analyzes the impact <strong>of</strong> source- <strong>and</strong> host-country<br />

characteristics on female immigrant labor supply. We f<strong>in</strong>d that immigrant women’s<br />

labor supply <strong>in</strong> their host country is positively associated with the labor force<br />

participation rate <strong>in</strong> their source country, which serves as a proxy for the country’s<br />

preferences <strong>and</strong> beliefs regard<strong>in</strong>g women’s roles. <strong>The</strong> effect <strong>of</strong> this cultural proxy on<br />

the labor supply <strong>of</strong> immigrant women is robust to controll<strong>in</strong>g for spousal, parental,<br />

<strong>and</strong> a variety <strong>of</strong> source-country characteristics. This result suggests that the culture<br />

<strong>and</strong> norms <strong>of</strong> their source country play an important role for immigrant women’s<br />

labor supply. Moreover, we f<strong>in</strong>d evidence for an impact <strong>of</strong> the host-country female<br />

labor force participation rate <strong>of</strong> natives on female immigrant labor supply.<br />

JEL Classifications: J16, J22, J61<br />

Keywords: female labor force participation, immigration, cultural transmission<br />

∗ <strong>The</strong> authors are grateful to Thomas K. Bauer <strong>and</strong> sem<strong>in</strong>ar participants at Victoria University<br />

<strong>of</strong> Well<strong>in</strong>gton, Motu Economic <strong>and</strong> Public Policy Research, the University <strong>of</strong> Otago, the Melbourne<br />

Institute <strong>of</strong> Applied Economic <strong>and</strong> Social Research <strong>and</strong> the Ruhr University Bochum for helpful comments<br />

<strong>and</strong> suggestions. All rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g errors are our own. – All correspondence to: Julia Bredtmann or<br />

Sebastian Otten, Department <strong>of</strong> Economics, Ruhr University Bochum, 44780 Bochum, Germany, E-mail:<br />

julia.bredtmann@rwi-essen.de or sebastian.otten@rwi-essen.de.


1 Introduction<br />

<strong>The</strong> first decade <strong>of</strong> the 21st century has seen large waves <strong>of</strong> migration from both with<strong>in</strong><br />

the EU <strong>and</strong> from outside it. In 2008, 3.8 million people migrated to <strong>and</strong> between the<br />

EU-27 Member States. Moreover, the share <strong>of</strong> immigrants that migrates from countries<br />

with substantial different cultures <strong>and</strong> traditions toward the European orig<strong>in</strong> population<br />

<strong>in</strong>creases. From the 47.3 million immigrants liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> EU Member States, about two-thirds<br />

were born outside their resident country, almost equally divided between America, Asia,<br />

Africa, <strong>and</strong> countries <strong>in</strong> Europe outside the EU-27 (European Commission, 2011). 1 S<strong>in</strong>ce<br />

we observe large variations <strong>in</strong> economic outcomes <strong>of</strong> immigrants across ethnic groups, an<br />

<strong>in</strong>tense political debate is tak<strong>in</strong>g place <strong>in</strong> Europe around migration issues with a focus<br />

on the costs <strong>and</strong> benefits <strong>of</strong> cultural diversity. 2<br />

At the same time, the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> life<br />

expectancy <strong>and</strong> low levels <strong>of</strong> fertility have triggered a process <strong>of</strong> population ag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> most<br />

EU Member States over the past decades. S<strong>in</strong>ce immigrants are usually younger than the<br />

<strong>in</strong>digenous population, immigration also has a significant impact on the age structure <strong>of</strong><br />

the population. [QUELLE!]<br />

As the share <strong>of</strong> the population that was born abroad rises <strong>and</strong> as the native-born<br />

work<strong>in</strong>g-age population decl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong> many European countries, issues concern<strong>in</strong>g the labor<br />

market <strong>in</strong>tegration <strong>of</strong> immigrants ga<strong>in</strong> attention by researchers <strong>and</strong> policymakers, which<br />

are usually discussed separately from the debate on cultural diversity. <strong>The</strong> question on<br />

labor market <strong>in</strong>tegration is especially relevant for immigrant women, s<strong>in</strong>ce their formal<br />

labor market participation is, on average, on a comparatively low level.<br />

Figure 1 shows a considerable variation <strong>in</strong> FLFP rates across the world. In particular,<br />

pronounced differences between the developed countries, which experienced a steady<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> FLFP s<strong>in</strong>ce the 1970s, <strong>and</strong> the less developed countries, which experienced<br />

none such trend so far, can be observed. Aga<strong>in</strong>st this background, it is important to note<br />

that European immigrants <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly come from countries that are characterized by<br />

relatively low FLFP rates as compared to the European average, such as the Middle East<br />

<strong>and</strong> Northern Africa countries. Differences <strong>in</strong> FLFP between typical immigration countries<br />

<strong>and</strong> immigrants’ countries <strong>of</strong> orig<strong>in</strong> may reflect differences <strong>in</strong> preferences regard<strong>in</strong>g women’s<br />

roles <strong>in</strong> family <strong>and</strong> society. Previous studies suggest that culture plays an important role<br />

<strong>in</strong> expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g differences <strong>in</strong> female labor market behavior across immigrants’ home-country<br />

groups (Antecol, 2000; Fernández <strong>and</strong> Fogli, 2009; Blau et al., 2011; Blau <strong>and</strong> Kahn, 2011).<br />

Furthermore, they reveal that these cultural effects also persist <strong>in</strong> the long run (Blau et al.,<br />

2011) <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>fluence the labor supply behavior <strong>of</strong> second- <strong>and</strong> higher-generation women<br />

(Antecol, 2000; Fernández <strong>and</strong> Fogli, 2009).<br />

But not only do we observe large variations <strong>in</strong> FLFP rates across immigrants’ source<br />

1 For an overview <strong>of</strong> the history <strong>of</strong> immigration <strong>in</strong>to Europe, see Bauer et al. (2000)<br />

2 QUELLEN: Deutschl<strong>and</strong>: Sarraz<strong>in</strong> Debatte, Debatte Multikulti ist gescheitert, ... <strong>and</strong>ere Länder?<br />

2


countries, we also observe large differences <strong>in</strong> FLFP rates across European countries,<br />

rang<strong>in</strong>g from 51.0 percent for Italy to 76.6 percent for Sweden. However, while some<br />

evidence exists that home-country FLFP <strong>in</strong>fluences first- <strong>and</strong> second-generation immigrant<br />

woman’s labor supply behavior <strong>in</strong> the host country, so far little is know about the role <strong>of</strong><br />

host-country FLFP on immigrant women’s behavior. In particular, it is <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest whether<br />

immigrant women assimilate to the labor market behavior <strong>of</strong> native women or whether<br />

their labor supply decisions are not affected by the FLFP <strong>in</strong> their host country at all.<br />

<strong>The</strong> aim <strong>of</strong> this paper is study the impact <strong>of</strong> source- <strong>and</strong> host-country characteristics<br />

on female immigrant labor supply. In our empirical analysis we employ data from four<br />

rounds <strong>of</strong> the European Social Survey (ESS), cover<strong>in</strong>g immigrants <strong>in</strong> 24 European countries<br />

surveyed between 2002 <strong>and</strong> 2010, which is augmented with an extensive set <strong>of</strong> aggregated<br />

source- <strong>and</strong> dest<strong>in</strong>ation-country characteristics.<br />

We f<strong>in</strong>d that women who migrate from countries with relatively high levels <strong>of</strong> female<br />

labor supply have a higher probability <strong>of</strong> participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the labor force <strong>in</strong> their respective<br />

host country. This positive effect <strong>of</strong> source country FLFP on women’s labor supply <strong>in</strong><br />

their host country holds for second-generation immigrants, though to a lesser extent.<br />

We are further able to show that most <strong>of</strong> this effect rema<strong>in</strong>s when we further control<br />

for the human capital <strong>of</strong> a woman’s partner, the past labor supply <strong>of</strong> her parents <strong>and</strong><br />

a variety <strong>of</strong> source-country characteristics that might be correlated with FLFP. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

results suggest that the culture <strong>and</strong> norms <strong>of</strong> the source country play an important role<br />

for immigrant women’s labor supply decisions. Moreover, we f<strong>in</strong>d evidence for an impact<br />

<strong>of</strong> the host-country female labor force participation rate <strong>of</strong> natives on female immigrant<br />

labor supply, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that immigrant women assimilate to the work behavior <strong>of</strong> natives.<br />

<strong>The</strong> rema<strong>in</strong>der <strong>of</strong> the paper is organized as follows. <strong>The</strong> next section provides a brief<br />

overview <strong>of</strong> the literature on the role <strong>of</strong> culture <strong>in</strong> economic behavior <strong>and</strong> presents the<br />

results <strong>of</strong> former studies analyz<strong>in</strong>g the labor supply <strong>of</strong> female immigrants. Section 3<br />

describes the data used, provides some descriptive evidence <strong>and</strong> expla<strong>in</strong>s the identification<br />

strategy <strong>of</strong> our analysis. We present <strong>and</strong> discuss the ma<strong>in</strong> estimation results <strong>in</strong> Section 4,<br />

while the results <strong>of</strong> several robustness checks are presented <strong>in</strong> Section 5. <strong>The</strong> f<strong>in</strong>al section<br />

summarizes the results <strong>and</strong> discusses their implications.<br />

2 Background<br />

<strong>The</strong> present study contributes to the evolv<strong>in</strong>g literature on the impact <strong>of</strong> culture on social<br />

<strong>and</strong> economic behavior. 3 In this str<strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> literature, differences <strong>in</strong> culture are broadly<br />

<strong>in</strong>terpreted as systematic variation <strong>in</strong> preferences <strong>and</strong> beliefs across time, space, or social<br />

3 For recent literature reviews on attempts to empirically identify the effects <strong>of</strong> culture on economic<br />

outcomes, see Guiso et al. (2006), Fernández (2008), <strong>and</strong> Fernández (2011).<br />

3


groups (Fernández, 2011). <strong>The</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> difficulty <strong>in</strong> identify<strong>in</strong>g the role <strong>of</strong> culture <strong>in</strong> economic<br />

behavior is to isolate it from those <strong>of</strong> the economic <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional environment <strong>in</strong> which<br />

economic decisions are taken. A possible solution to this problem is brought about by<br />

what Fernández (2011) refers to as the epidemiological approach. <strong>The</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> idea <strong>of</strong> this<br />

approach is to identify the effect <strong>of</strong> culture through the variation <strong>in</strong> economic outcomes <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>dividuals who share the same economic <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional environment, but whose social<br />

beliefs are potentially different. One way to apply this approach is to focus on the economic<br />

behavior <strong>of</strong> immigrants. When <strong>in</strong>dividuals emigrate, they may take some aspects <strong>of</strong> their<br />

culture with them <strong>and</strong> transmit them <strong>in</strong>tergenerationally, but they live <strong>in</strong> the economic<br />

<strong>and</strong> formal <strong>in</strong>stitutional environment <strong>of</strong> the host country. Study<strong>in</strong>g the economic behavior<br />

<strong>of</strong> immigrants from different countries <strong>of</strong> orig<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> their host country may therefore be a<br />

useful strategy to isolate culture from strictly economic <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional effects.<br />

In this paper, we study the effect <strong>of</strong> culture on the labor supply <strong>of</strong> first- <strong>and</strong> secondgeneration<br />

female immigrants <strong>in</strong> Europe. In do<strong>in</strong>g so, our study builds on research that<br />

has exam<strong>in</strong>ed the effect <strong>of</strong> home-country characteristics on U.S. immigrant women’s labor<br />

supply. 4 An early attempt to identify the effect <strong>of</strong> culture on immigrant labor supply<br />

is the study by Reimers (1985), who uses ethnic dummy variables to exam<strong>in</strong>e whether<br />

cultural factors play a direct role <strong>in</strong> married women’s labor force participation <strong>in</strong> the U.S.<br />

As Reimers’ approach suffers from the disadvantage <strong>of</strong> not be<strong>in</strong>g explicit as to why<br />

ethnicity matters, more recent studies address this limitation by us<strong>in</strong>g quantitative variables<br />

as proxies for culture. In particular, they use past values <strong>of</strong> FLFP rates <strong>in</strong> the immigrant’s<br />

country <strong>of</strong> orig<strong>in</strong> as a cultural proxy. As Fernández <strong>and</strong> Fogli (2009) po<strong>in</strong>t out, the ma<strong>in</strong><br />

idea for us<strong>in</strong>g this aggregate variable is that it reflects the market work decisions <strong>of</strong> women<br />

<strong>in</strong> the source country, which (<strong>in</strong> addition to each woman’s <strong>in</strong>dividual characteristics)<br />

depend on the economic <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional environment as well as the preferences <strong>and</strong><br />

beliefs with<strong>in</strong> the country. While the economic <strong>and</strong> (formal) <strong>in</strong>stitutional conditions <strong>of</strong> the<br />

country <strong>of</strong> orig<strong>in</strong> should no longer be relevant for emigrated women, the preferences <strong>and</strong><br />

beliefs embodied <strong>in</strong> this variable may still matter. Hence, if this aggregate variable has<br />

explanatory power for the variation <strong>in</strong> the labor market behavior <strong>of</strong> immigrant women,<br />

even after controll<strong>in</strong>g for their <strong>in</strong>dividual economic attributes, only the cultural component<br />

<strong>of</strong> this variable can be responsible for this correlation.<br />

<strong>The</strong> first study to analyze the effect <strong>of</strong> source-country FLFP rates on the work outcomes<br />

<strong>of</strong> female immigrants is the study by Antecol (2000), who f<strong>in</strong>ds the source-country FLFP<br />

rates to be positively correlated with the LFP <strong>of</strong> first-generation immigrant women <strong>in</strong><br />

the U.S. <strong>The</strong>se f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs, though weaker, even hold for second- <strong>and</strong> higher-generation<br />

4 <strong>The</strong> role <strong>of</strong> source-country variables, <strong>in</strong> different contexts, has been exam<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> several studies. For<br />

example, Borjas (1987) on the native/immigrant wage differential, Blau (1992) on the fertility behavior<br />

among first-generation immigrant women, <strong>and</strong> Antecol (2001) on the role <strong>of</strong> home-country variables <strong>in</strong><br />

expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g variation <strong>in</strong> the gender wage gap across home-country groups with<strong>in</strong> the U.S.<br />

4


immigrants. However, as Fernández <strong>and</strong> Fogli (2009) po<strong>in</strong>t out, these results might<br />

be driven by unobserved heterogeneity, as the analysis does not control for important<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividual characteristics such as years <strong>of</strong> education or parental background.<br />

In their study on the work <strong>and</strong> fertility behavior <strong>of</strong> US-born daughters <strong>of</strong> immigrants<br />

to the U.S., Fernández <strong>and</strong> Fogli (2009) use various measures <strong>of</strong> average parental education<br />

<strong>and</strong> average education <strong>of</strong> the immigrant group to control for human capital factors. <strong>The</strong>y<br />

f<strong>in</strong>d that the labor supply <strong>and</strong> fertility behavior <strong>of</strong> second-generation female immigrants is<br />

positively associated with both FLFP rates <strong>and</strong> fertility rates <strong>in</strong> their parents’ country <strong>of</strong><br />

orig<strong>in</strong>. <strong>The</strong> authors also show that the husb<strong>and</strong>’s culture, as proxied by the FLFP rate <strong>in</strong><br />

the country <strong>of</strong> ancestry <strong>of</strong> his parents, has a large impact on his wife’s labor supply.<br />

<strong>The</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> the immigrant women’s own labor supply prior to migrat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> the<br />

FLFP rate <strong>in</strong> their source country is <strong>in</strong>vestigated by Blau <strong>and</strong> Kahn (2011) to provide<br />

evidence on the role <strong>of</strong> human capital <strong>and</strong> culture <strong>in</strong> affect<strong>in</strong>g immigrants’ labor supply <strong>and</strong><br />

wages <strong>in</strong> the U.S. <strong>The</strong>ir results provide further evidence that women from source countries<br />

with relatively high levels <strong>of</strong> FLFP have higher work<strong>in</strong>g hours <strong>in</strong> the U.S. Moreover, they<br />

reveal that most <strong>of</strong> this effect rema<strong>in</strong>s even when controll<strong>in</strong>g for the immigrant’s own<br />

pre-migration labor supply, which itself strongly affects immigrant’s labor supply <strong>in</strong> the<br />

U.S. In a similar study, Blau et al. (2011) show that source-country FLFP rates are also<br />

positively associated with immigrant women’s labor supply assimilation pr<strong>of</strong>iles, with those<br />

com<strong>in</strong>g from high female labor supply countries eventually assimilat<strong>in</strong>g fully to native<br />

labor supply levels.<br />

<strong>The</strong> results <strong>of</strong> these studies suggest an important role for source-country culture <strong>in</strong><br />

affect<strong>in</strong>g immigrant women’s labor supply. However, the effect <strong>of</strong> culture on immigrants’<br />

behavior might weaken as immigrants assimilate to the culture <strong>of</strong> their host country. This<br />

argument is based on Fernández’ notion that noth<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the conception <strong>of</strong> culture considers<br />

it as static or slow chang<strong>in</strong>g. In fact, culture might change over time <strong>and</strong> the speed <strong>of</strong><br />

cultural change depends on how quickly social beliefs <strong>and</strong> preferences alter over time,<br />

which <strong>in</strong> turn depends on the <strong>in</strong>dividuals’ environment (Fernández, 2011).<br />

A salient example <strong>of</strong> a cultural change is seen <strong>in</strong> the evolution <strong>of</strong> social attitudes <strong>and</strong><br />

beliefs towards women’s market work, which serves as one possible explanation for the<br />

dramatic change <strong>in</strong> female labor force participation over time. In order to expla<strong>in</strong> the<br />

sharp <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> female labor force participation rates, Fogli <strong>and</strong> Veldkamp (2011) as<br />

well as Fernández (2012) develop a model <strong>of</strong> cultural change that is brought about by a<br />

process <strong>of</strong> endogenous <strong>in</strong>tergenerational learn<strong>in</strong>g. In their models, women are assumed<br />

to learn about the long-term pay<strong>of</strong>fs <strong>of</strong> work<strong>in</strong>g by observ<strong>in</strong>g (noisy) private <strong>and</strong> public<br />

signals <strong>and</strong> then make a work decision. When very few women participate <strong>in</strong> the labor<br />

market, the nois<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>of</strong> the public signal is high <strong>and</strong> learn<strong>in</strong>g is very slow. As <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

accumulates <strong>in</strong> some regions, the signal improves <strong>and</strong> beliefs about work become more<br />

5


positive. As a result, the proportion <strong>of</strong> women who work <strong>in</strong> that region <strong>in</strong>creases. 5<br />

While it is not the aim <strong>of</strong> this paper to provide an empirical test <strong>of</strong> these theories,<br />

their ma<strong>in</strong> implications can be easily applied to female immigrant labor supply decisions.<br />

By observ<strong>in</strong>g other work<strong>in</strong>g women <strong>in</strong> the host country, female immigrants might change<br />

their attitudes <strong>and</strong> beliefs regard<strong>in</strong>g women’s role <strong>in</strong> the workplace <strong>and</strong> gradually adapt<br />

to the behavior <strong>of</strong> native women. <strong>The</strong> higher thereby, all else equal, the proportion <strong>of</strong><br />

work<strong>in</strong>g women <strong>in</strong> the host country, the more positive the beliefs about work <strong>and</strong> the<br />

higher the probability that an immigrant women decides to participate <strong>in</strong> the labor market.<br />

Assess<strong>in</strong>g the relationship between host-country FLFP <strong>and</strong> the labor supply <strong>of</strong> female<br />

immigrants might therefore provide some <strong>in</strong>sights <strong>in</strong>to whether immigrant women change<br />

their attitudes <strong>and</strong> beliefs <strong>and</strong> assimilate to the labor market behavior <strong>of</strong> natives.<br />

While – s<strong>in</strong>ce the sem<strong>in</strong>al work <strong>of</strong> Chiswick (1978) – a sizable body <strong>of</strong> literature has<br />

evolved that exam<strong>in</strong>es immigrant-native assimilation patterns with<strong>in</strong> a given dest<strong>in</strong>ation<br />

country, studies that analyze immigrants <strong>in</strong> different resident countries to provide evidence<br />

on the role <strong>of</strong> host-country characteristics <strong>in</strong> immigrant behavior are scarce. <strong>The</strong> only<br />

study that aims at assess<strong>in</strong>g the effect <strong>of</strong> host-country FLFP on female immigrant labor<br />

supply is Kok et al. (2011) for the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. However, as their study is based on<br />

immigrants with<strong>in</strong> a s<strong>in</strong>gle country, their identification <strong>of</strong> the host-country effect does not<br />

rely on differences <strong>in</strong> FLFP rates between immigrants’ countries <strong>of</strong> residence, but on the<br />

difference <strong>in</strong> levels <strong>and</strong> speed <strong>of</strong> adjustment between different cohorts <strong>of</strong> immigrants. In<br />

particular, they use the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the FLFP rate over successive birth cohorts <strong>of</strong> native<br />

women as a proxy for Dutch culture. <strong>The</strong> authors’ results suggests that both differences<br />

<strong>in</strong> home-country female participation <strong>and</strong> the trend <strong>in</strong> native female participation, as<br />

a measure for host-country culture, have an impact on the participation <strong>of</strong> immigrant<br />

women. <strong>The</strong> authors conclude from these results that host-country participation is at<br />

least as important as home-country participation <strong>in</strong> affect<strong>in</strong>g immigrants’ labor supply<br />

decisions.<br />

Although a positive relationship between host-country FLFP rates <strong>and</strong> immigrant<br />

women’s labor supply might be <strong>in</strong>dicative <strong>of</strong> immigrant women adapt<strong>in</strong>g to the culture <strong>of</strong><br />

the host country <strong>and</strong> therefore to the work behavior <strong>of</strong> natives, other explanations are<br />

also possible. As a given woman’s decision to participate <strong>in</strong> the labor market does not<br />

only depend on her preferences <strong>and</strong> beliefs, but also on a whole series <strong>of</strong> economic <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>stitutional factors that may differ across countries, FLFP at the aggregate level will not<br />

only reflect a country’s cultural environment, but its economic <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional conditions<br />

5 <strong>The</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> difference between the two models lies <strong>in</strong> the assumption regard<strong>in</strong>g the driv<strong>in</strong>g force beh<strong>in</strong>d<br />

female labor supply dynamics. While Fernández (2012) assumes that women start with biased, pessimistic<br />

beliefs about work<strong>in</strong>g women which become more positive as participation rises, Fogli <strong>and</strong> Veldkamp<br />

(2011) assume that women start with unbiased beliefs, but face uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty about the effects <strong>of</strong> maternal<br />

employment on their children, which falls as <strong>in</strong>formation accumulates.<br />

6


as well. However, although we are not able to identify the source <strong>of</strong> assimilation, the effect<br />

<strong>of</strong> the LFP rate <strong>of</strong> native women <strong>in</strong> a given country on the work behavior <strong>of</strong> immigrants is<br />

still <strong>in</strong>dicative as to whether immigrants adapt to the work behavior <strong>of</strong> natives.<br />

In the present paper, we make a number <strong>of</strong> contributions to the exist<strong>in</strong>g literature. First,<br />

we contribute to the literature on the role <strong>of</strong> source-country culture on female immigrant<br />

labor supply. While previous literature has exclusively focused on the U.S. 6 , we analyze<br />

the labor market behavior <strong>of</strong> immigrants <strong>in</strong> 24 European countries, thereby provid<strong>in</strong>g<br />

some first evidence for Europe. Second, we take advantage <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> cross-country<br />

data as compared to s<strong>in</strong>gle-country data to analyze immigrant labor supply behavior.<br />

Observ<strong>in</strong>g immigrants <strong>in</strong> different dest<strong>in</strong>ation countries enables us to provide evidence<br />

on the relationship between host-country FLFP <strong>and</strong> immigrants labor force participation,<br />

thereby shedd<strong>in</strong>g light on assimilation patterns <strong>of</strong> immigrants to the work behavior <strong>of</strong><br />

natives. Effectively, we are able to disentangle the effects <strong>of</strong> source- <strong>and</strong> host-country<br />

FLFP on immigrant woman’s labor supply. In contrast to earlier work, our research design<br />

allows us to control for a variety <strong>of</strong> source- <strong>and</strong> the host-country characteristics beyond<br />

FLFP rates. While controll<strong>in</strong>g for a large set <strong>of</strong> macroeconomic <strong>in</strong>dicators <strong>in</strong>creases the<br />

likelihood that we estimate the true effect <strong>of</strong> source- <strong>and</strong> host-country FLFP on immigrant<br />

women’s labor supply, assess<strong>in</strong>g the effect <strong>of</strong> these economic <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional conditions<br />

on immigrant behavior is <strong>of</strong> considerable <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> itself. Lastly, we conduct our analysis<br />

separately for first- <strong>and</strong> second-generation immigrants. As Fernández <strong>and</strong> Fogli (2009)<br />

outl<strong>in</strong>e, the effect <strong>of</strong> source-country culture on economic actions should be weaker for<br />

second-generation immigrants than for first-generation immigrants, as cultural transmission<br />

is restricted mostly to parents <strong>and</strong> ethnic social networks rather than operat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> society<br />

at large (e.g., schools, media, etc.). On the other h<strong>and</strong>, we expect the effect <strong>of</strong> host-country<br />

FLFP to be stronger for second-generation immigrants than for first-generation immigrants,<br />

as second-generation immigrants grow up with the culture <strong>of</strong> their host country. Hence,<br />

analyz<strong>in</strong>g the differ<strong>in</strong>g effects <strong>of</strong> source- <strong>and</strong> host-country characteristics on the labor<br />

supply <strong>of</strong> first- <strong>and</strong> second-generation immigrants sheds further light on cultural <strong>and</strong><br />

economic assimilation patterns.<br />

3 Data, Descriptive Statistics <strong>and</strong> Method<br />

3.1 <strong>The</strong> ESS<br />

Our basic data source is the European Social Survey (ESS), a multi-country biennial<br />

cross-sectional survey funded jo<strong>in</strong>tly by the European Commission, the European Science<br />

Foundation <strong>and</strong> academic fund<strong>in</strong>g bodies <strong>in</strong> each participat<strong>in</strong>g country. <strong>The</strong> central aim<br />

6 With exception <strong>of</strong> the paper by Kok et al. (2011) for the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

7


<strong>of</strong> the ESS is to gather data about people’s social values, cultural norms <strong>and</strong> behavioral<br />

patterns with<strong>in</strong> Europe. <strong>The</strong> first round <strong>of</strong> the ESS was fielded <strong>in</strong> 2002/2003. Up to<br />

now, five waves are available, cover<strong>in</strong>g a total <strong>of</strong> 33 nations. <strong>The</strong> survey consists <strong>of</strong> two<br />

elements – a basic <strong>in</strong>terview questionnaire conducted <strong>in</strong> every round <strong>and</strong> a supplementary<br />

questionnaire devoted to specific topics, which changes over time.<br />

In particular, the ESS conta<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>formation on the country <strong>of</strong> birth <strong>of</strong> both the<br />

respondent <strong>and</strong> the parents, which allows us to precisely identify the source country <strong>of</strong><br />

both first- <strong>and</strong> second-generation immigrants. We def<strong>in</strong>e first-generation immigrants as<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividuals born outside their host country. Respondents are classified as second-generation<br />

immigrants if one or both parents are born outside the host country. For first-generation<br />

immigrants, the data further conta<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation on when the immigrant left his/her<br />

source country. We use this <strong>in</strong>formation to match source-country characteristics from a<br />

time-series cross-country data base we constructed, as described <strong>in</strong> more detail below.<br />

We use the cumulative ESS data, which pools the common <strong>in</strong>formation from the first<br />

to the fourth ESS round, lead<strong>in</strong>g to a total <strong>of</strong> 29 countries <strong>and</strong> roughly 189,00 <strong>in</strong>dividuals.<br />

We exclude countries not belong<strong>in</strong>g to the European Union (except for Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> Norway) 7 as well as those for which the number <strong>of</strong> surveyed female immigrants is<br />

particularly small (lower than 20 <strong>in</strong>dividuals). Because we are ultimately <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestigat<strong>in</strong>g immigrant women’s labor supply decisions, we consider <strong>in</strong>dividuals aged 26<br />

to 59 years only. Our f<strong>in</strong>al sample consists <strong>of</strong> 6,168 immigrants <strong>in</strong> 24 countries, 8 <strong>of</strong> which<br />

roughly 63% are first-generation <strong>and</strong> 37% are second-generation immigrants. 9<br />

3.2 Individual Data<br />

Our ma<strong>in</strong> variable <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest, which serves as the dependent variable <strong>in</strong> all our regressions,<br />

is an <strong>in</strong>dividual’s labor market status at time <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terview (lfp ijk ). In particular, lfp ijk<br />

is a b<strong>in</strong>ary <strong>in</strong>dicator that takes value 1 if immigrant woman i from source country j <strong>in</strong> host<br />

country k stated that her ma<strong>in</strong> activity with<strong>in</strong> the past 7 days was either be<strong>in</strong>g employed<br />

or be<strong>in</strong>g unemployed while actively look<strong>in</strong>g for a job, <strong>and</strong> 0 otherwise.<br />

<strong>The</strong> ESS data conta<strong>in</strong> detailed <strong>in</strong>formation on the respondent’s socio-demographic<br />

characteristics as well as the composition <strong>of</strong> his or her household. Based on this <strong>in</strong>formation,<br />

we generate the follow<strong>in</strong>g variables which serve as controls <strong>in</strong> all our regressions: age (4<br />

categories), highest level <strong>of</strong> education (primary, secondary or tertiary education), partner<br />

liv<strong>in</strong>g with<strong>in</strong> the household, number <strong>of</strong> household members, <strong>and</strong> youngest child is 0-2 years<br />

7 In particular, we exclude immigrants <strong>in</strong> Israel, Russia, Turkey, <strong>and</strong> the Ukra<strong>in</strong>e.<br />

8 <strong>The</strong> countries <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> our sample are Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, the Czech Republic, Denmark,<br />

Estonia, F<strong>in</strong>l<strong>and</strong>, France, Great Brita<strong>in</strong>, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Irel<strong>and</strong>, Italy, Lithuania, Luxembourg,<br />

the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Norway, Pol<strong>and</strong>, Portugal, Slovenia, Spa<strong>in</strong>, Sweden, <strong>and</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong>.<br />

9 <strong>The</strong> low share <strong>of</strong> second-generation immigrants <strong>in</strong> our data can be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the fact that<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation on the parents’ country <strong>of</strong> birth is only <strong>in</strong>cluded from round 2 <strong>of</strong> the ESS onwards.<br />

8


<strong>and</strong> 3-5 years, respectively.<br />

For first-generation immigrants, we further <strong>in</strong>clude some immigration-specific variables.<br />

While both an immigrant woman’s duration <strong>of</strong> residence <strong>and</strong> her age at the time <strong>of</strong><br />

migration are likely to affect her work behavior <strong>in</strong> the host-country, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g both<br />

variables while still controll<strong>in</strong>g for age is not possible due to perfect correlation <strong>of</strong> these<br />

variables.<br />

We attempt to circumvent this problem by <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g age <strong>and</strong> years s<strong>in</strong>ce<br />

migration <strong>in</strong> categories, allow<strong>in</strong>g us to further add a dummy variable <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g whether a<br />

women immigrated after age 18. <strong>The</strong> <strong>in</strong>clusion <strong>of</strong> the latter variable allows us to control<br />

for whether a woman obta<strong>in</strong>ed her (primary <strong>and</strong> secondary) education <strong>in</strong> her host or<br />

<strong>in</strong> her home country, with the latter presumably be<strong>in</strong>g less affected by home-country<br />

characteristics <strong>and</strong> more similar to natives when they reach adulthood than those migrat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

as adults.<br />

An important issue that has to be considered when analyz<strong>in</strong>g the labor supply <strong>of</strong><br />

immigrants across different host countries is that immigrants might face restrictions <strong>in</strong><br />

their access to the host country’s labor market. Specifically, immigrants from non-EU<br />

countries might not be allowed to work <strong>in</strong> their host country <strong>in</strong> the first years after arrival.<br />

In order to dist<strong>in</strong>guish immigrants that are permitted to work from day one <strong>in</strong> their host<br />

country from those who might face restrictions to do so, we <strong>in</strong>clude a dummy variable<br />

that <strong>in</strong>dicates whether a woman underlies the “right on free movement <strong>of</strong> workers” at the<br />

time <strong>of</strong> observation. <strong>The</strong> right on free movement <strong>of</strong> workers is a fundamental pr<strong>in</strong>ciple<br />

enshr<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> Article 45 <strong>of</strong> the Treaty on the Function<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> the European Union, which<br />

generally permits workers to search for employment, to be employed <strong>and</strong> to reside <strong>in</strong> any<br />

other Member State <strong>of</strong> the European Union (European Commission, 2010). 10<br />

Lastly, we <strong>in</strong>clude a dummy variable <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g whether an immigrant speaks the host<br />

country’s language. This <strong>in</strong>formation is obta<strong>in</strong>ed from a question <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the ESS<br />

that asks respondents to name up to two languages they speak most <strong>of</strong>ten at home. <strong>The</strong><br />

variable takes value 1 if one <strong>of</strong> these two languages is also one <strong>of</strong> the <strong>of</strong>ficial languages <strong>of</strong><br />

the immigrant’s country <strong>of</strong> residence.<br />

Although the ESS is not designed as a household survey, but is <strong>in</strong> effect an <strong>in</strong>dividual<br />

survey, it conta<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>formation on a respondent’s partner. Controll<strong>in</strong>g for partner characteristics<br />

<strong>in</strong> women’s labor supply decisions is mean<strong>in</strong>gful for two reasons. First, for those<br />

liv<strong>in</strong>g with a partner some k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> jo<strong>in</strong>t decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g process with respect to labor<br />

10 While the right on free movement <strong>of</strong> workers generally applies to all immigrants migrat<strong>in</strong>g with<strong>in</strong> the<br />

European Union, there is a clause about a transition period before workers from the new Member States<br />

can be employed on equal, non-discrim<strong>in</strong>atory terms <strong>in</strong> the old Member States. <strong>The</strong> old Member States<br />

have the right to impose such transitional period for 2 years, then to decide if to extend it for additional<br />

3 years, <strong>and</strong> then, if there is serious pro<strong>of</strong> that labor from new Member States would be disruptive to<br />

the market <strong>in</strong> the old Member States then the period can be extended for the last time for 2 more years.<br />

Furthermore, citizens <strong>of</strong> the Member States <strong>of</strong> the European Economic Area <strong>and</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong> have the<br />

same right <strong>of</strong> freedom <strong>of</strong> movement <strong>and</strong> these countries are treated as old Member States <strong>in</strong>side the EEA<br />

(European Commission, 2003, 2005).<br />

9


supply <strong>and</strong> household production has to be assumed. 11<br />

Independent on which k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong><br />

model is assumed to underlie a couple’s decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g process, women are predicted<br />

to be less likely to participate the higher the partner’s earn<strong>in</strong>gs potential. Second, there<br />

is evidence <strong>of</strong> assortative mat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the marriage market, i.e., more educated (<strong>and</strong> hence<br />

higher <strong>in</strong>come) men tend to be married to more educated women (see, e.g., Pencavel, 1998).<br />

<strong>The</strong> husb<strong>and</strong>’s higher <strong>in</strong>come will decrease the <strong>in</strong>centives for his wife to engage <strong>in</strong> market<br />

work <strong>and</strong>, <strong>in</strong> this way, mask the strength <strong>of</strong> the effect <strong>of</strong> source-country culture on women’s<br />

labor supply decisions. We attempt to capture the impact <strong>of</strong> both assortative mat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong><br />

jo<strong>in</strong>t decision mak<strong>in</strong>g with<strong>in</strong> the household by controll<strong>in</strong>g for the partner’s highest level <strong>of</strong><br />

education <strong>and</strong> his work<strong>in</strong>g hours. However, as these variables are endogenous to a women’s<br />

labor force participation decision, we will not <strong>in</strong>clude them <strong>in</strong> our basic regression model.<br />

While the aforementioned variables capture the human capital <strong>of</strong> a woman’s partner,<br />

the partner’s cultural background is also likely to play a role <strong>in</strong> her labor force participation<br />

decision. Fernández <strong>and</strong> Fogli (2009) show that a husb<strong>and</strong>’s culture, as measured by the<br />

LFPR <strong>in</strong> his father’s country <strong>of</strong> birth, is an important determ<strong>in</strong>ant <strong>of</strong> his wife’s employment<br />

decision. More generally, Fernández et al. (2004) as well as Johnston et al. (2012) f<strong>in</strong>d<br />

evidence that an important factor expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g whether a man’s wife works is whether his<br />

own mother worked when he was grow<strong>in</strong>g up. <strong>The</strong> authors argue that a mother’s decision<br />

to work or not is <strong>in</strong>fluenced by her beliefs about women’s roles, which then have been<br />

transmitted to her son <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>fluenced any household decision affect<strong>in</strong>g his wife’s work<br />

outcome. Unfortunately, the ESS data do neither conta<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation on a partner’s<br />

cultural background (i.e., his immigration status <strong>and</strong> his country <strong>of</strong> orig<strong>in</strong>), nor do they<br />

<strong>in</strong>clude <strong>in</strong>formation on his parent’s employment outcomes, mak<strong>in</strong>g it impossible to control<br />

for any k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> assortative mat<strong>in</strong>g with respect to perceptions about gender roles. In<br />

particular, a woman who would like to work is presumably more likely to marry a man<br />

who would be <strong>in</strong> agreement with these choices. Given that the FLFPR <strong>in</strong> the source<br />

country serves as proxy for an <strong>in</strong>dividual’s beliefs regard<strong>in</strong>g women’s role <strong>in</strong> society, we<br />

would assume that women from high FLFPR countries will be more likely to marry men<br />

from high FLFPR countries. Hence, we have to keep <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d that part <strong>of</strong> the effect <strong>of</strong> our<br />

cultural proxy might not capture a direct impact on an immigrant women’s decision to<br />

participate <strong>in</strong> the labor market. Rather, it might reflect an <strong>in</strong>direct effect <strong>of</strong> a woman’s<br />

mat<strong>in</strong>g decision, which is <strong>in</strong>fluenced by her beliefs regard<strong>in</strong>g gender roles <strong>and</strong> ultimately<br />

effects her decision about market work.<br />

As Blau <strong>and</strong> Kahn (2011) show, a strong predictor <strong>of</strong> an immigrant women’s labor<br />

supply <strong>in</strong> the host country is their own labor supply <strong>in</strong> the source country prior to migrat<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

If immigrant women from high FLFP countries have more work experience prior to their<br />

11 <strong>The</strong> economic theory <strong>of</strong> jo<strong>in</strong>t labor supply decisions with<strong>in</strong> the household was <strong>in</strong>itiated by Becker<br />

(1965) <strong>and</strong> developed, <strong>in</strong>t. al., by Gronau (1977), Manser <strong>and</strong> Brown (1980) <strong>and</strong> McElroy <strong>and</strong> Horney<br />

(1981).<br />

10


arrival <strong>in</strong> the host country, then the observed effect <strong>of</strong> source-country FLFP may be due<br />

to the relatively high levels <strong>of</strong> job-related human capital that they accumulated before<br />

migration. Hence, without tak<strong>in</strong>g the immigrants’ pre-migration labor supply <strong>in</strong>to account,<br />

we cannot be sure whether a positive relationship between high source-country FLFP <strong>and</strong><br />

immigrant women’s labor supply <strong>in</strong> their host country provides evidence for an effect <strong>of</strong><br />

broader culture on immigrants’ labor market behavior, or whether it simply reflects the<br />

immigrant woman’s own pre-migration behavior.<br />

While the ESS data do not allow to control for an immigrant’s own labour supply <strong>in</strong><br />

the source country, they provide <strong>in</strong>formation on the human capital <strong>and</strong> labor supply <strong>of</strong><br />

the immigrant’s parents. In particular, each respondent is asked about (i) his mother’s<br />

<strong>and</strong> father’s highest level <strong>of</strong> education <strong>and</strong> (ii) their labor market status at the time the<br />

respondent was 14 years old. As the empirical literature on <strong>in</strong>tergenerational mobility<br />

has consistently documented a high persistence between parents’ <strong>and</strong> children’s economic<br />

outcomes 12 , we use these <strong>in</strong>dicators as a proxy for the immigrant’s own labor supply prior<br />

to migration. In do<strong>in</strong>g so, we are able to test whether the effect <strong>of</strong> source-country FLFP<br />

on immigrant labor supply persists even if the immigrant’s pre-migration human capital is<br />

controlled for.<br />

3.3 Aggregated Data<br />

For the analysis <strong>of</strong> source- <strong>and</strong> host-country effects, we augment our <strong>in</strong>dividual data with<br />

an extensive time-series, cross-country database <strong>of</strong> aggregated source- <strong>and</strong> host-country<br />

characteristics. 13<br />

While for first-generation immigrants source-country characteristics<br />

refer to the immigrant’s country <strong>of</strong> ancestry, the source-country characteristics for secondgeneration<br />

immigrants refer to the country <strong>of</strong> birth <strong>of</strong> the father or the mother <strong>of</strong> the<br />

immigrant, depend<strong>in</strong>g on who <strong>of</strong> the two was born <strong>in</strong> a foreign country. In case both<br />

parents were born outside the host country <strong>and</strong> emigrated from different countries, we use<br />

the mother’s birthplace to assign the country-<strong>of</strong>-ancestry <strong>in</strong>dicators to second-generation<br />

women, as we believe the <strong>in</strong>tergenerational transmission <strong>of</strong> beliefs <strong>and</strong> values regard<strong>in</strong>g<br />

women’s role <strong>in</strong> society to be stronger between mothers <strong>and</strong> daughters than between<br />

fathers <strong>and</strong> daughters. 14<br />

For both first- <strong>and</strong> second-generation immigrants, the host-country <strong>in</strong>dicators were<br />

assigned to immigrants based on their country <strong>of</strong> dest<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>and</strong> the year <strong>of</strong> observation<br />

(2002 to 2011). With respect to the source-country characteristics, however, the optimal<br />

po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> time from which to take these <strong>in</strong>dicators is not obvious.<br />

12 For a recent overview <strong>of</strong> studies on <strong>in</strong>tergenerational mobility, see Black <strong>and</strong> Devereux (2011).<br />

13 See Table A1 <strong>in</strong> the Appendix for a detailed description <strong>of</strong> the macro data.<br />

14 In our sample, 6% <strong>of</strong> the second-generation female immigrants have parents who are born <strong>in</strong><br />

different source countries. As a robustness check, we have also run our regressions by us<strong>in</strong>g the country<br />

characteristics <strong>of</strong> the father’s birthplace for these women. <strong>The</strong> results <strong>of</strong> our regressions rema<strong>in</strong> unaffected.<br />

11


For first-generation immigrants, we follow Bis<strong>in</strong> et al. (2011), Blau <strong>and</strong> Kahn (2011),<br />

<strong>and</strong> Blau et al. (2011) <strong>and</strong> measure source-country variables at the time these immigrants<br />

left that country. In do<strong>in</strong>g so, we are able to measure the norms <strong>and</strong> values immigrants<br />

grew up with <strong>and</strong> carry to their host country. We calculate the year the immigrant left<br />

the home country by us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation on the year <strong>of</strong> observation <strong>and</strong> the immigrant’s<br />

years s<strong>in</strong>ce arrival <strong>in</strong> the host country. 15 S<strong>in</strong>ce the latter is not a cont<strong>in</strong>uous variable but<br />

is subdivided <strong>in</strong> predef<strong>in</strong>ed categories, we set years s<strong>in</strong>ce migration equal to the mid-po<strong>in</strong>t<br />

<strong>of</strong> each <strong>in</strong>terval <strong>and</strong> to the lower bound <strong>of</strong> the top <strong>in</strong>terval (i.e., 20 years). Thus, our<br />

source-country data for first-generation immigrants span the years 1982 to 2010.<br />

As Fernández <strong>and</strong> Fogli (2009) outl<strong>in</strong>e, the optimal po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>of</strong> time from which to take<br />

the respective values for second-generation immigrants is not obvious. On the one h<strong>and</strong>, it<br />

could be argued that the values <strong>of</strong> the culture proxy variables measured at the time the<br />

immigrant’s parents left their home country would best reflect the culture <strong>of</strong> the country<br />

<strong>of</strong> ancestry. <strong>The</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> problem with assign<strong>in</strong>g the source-country characteristics based on<br />

the year the immigrant’s parents left the country is that this <strong>in</strong>formation is not <strong>in</strong>cluded<br />

<strong>in</strong> our data. However, even if we were able to observe the parents’ year <strong>of</strong> arrival, data<br />

limitations would permit us to use years prior to 1960, s<strong>in</strong>ce values for most <strong>of</strong> our macro<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicators are not available prior to that year. Fernández <strong>and</strong> Fogli (2009) circumvent<br />

this problem by us<strong>in</strong>g the current values <strong>of</strong> the source country <strong>in</strong>dicators, argu<strong>in</strong>g that<br />

the values that parents <strong>and</strong> society transmit to second-generation immigrants might be<br />

best reflected by a comparison <strong>of</strong> what the counterparts <strong>of</strong> these women are do<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the<br />

country <strong>of</strong> ancestry at the time <strong>of</strong> observation. We follow this approach, thereby mak<strong>in</strong>g<br />

sure that the macro <strong>in</strong>dicators are available for the majority <strong>of</strong> the source countries <strong>in</strong> our<br />

sample, as they span the years 2002 to 2011 only. A possible drawback <strong>of</strong> the outl<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

assignment rules is that we treat first- <strong>and</strong> second-generation immigrants differently, i.e.,<br />

we use current values <strong>of</strong> the macro <strong>in</strong>dicators for second-generation immigrants, while we<br />

assign past values <strong>of</strong> these <strong>in</strong>dicators to first-generation immigrants, mak<strong>in</strong>g a comparison<br />

<strong>of</strong> the behavior <strong>of</strong> both groups problematic. In order to assure that our results are not<br />

driven by these assignment rules, we therefore perform sensitivity analyses <strong>in</strong> which we use<br />

current <strong>in</strong>stead <strong>of</strong> past values <strong>of</strong> all macro <strong>in</strong>dicators for both first- <strong>and</strong> second-generation<br />

immigrants.<br />

<strong>The</strong> explanatory variables <strong>of</strong> our ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest are F LF P R j <strong>and</strong> F LF P R k , the female<br />

labor force participation rates <strong>of</strong> the immigrant’s source <strong>and</strong> host country, respectively.<br />

<strong>The</strong> source-country FLFP rate covers the rate <strong>of</strong> the economically active population for<br />

women aged 15 to 65 <strong>in</strong> the immigrant’s country <strong>of</strong> ancestry. We apply this age restriction<br />

<strong>in</strong> order to avoid the FLFPR to vary with the share <strong>of</strong> elderly among the population,<br />

15 As previous studies, we thereby implicitly assume that the year the immigrant left her home country<br />

equals the year she arrived <strong>in</strong> the host country. I.e., we assume that immigrants directly move from their<br />

source country to their dest<strong>in</strong>ation country <strong>and</strong> thus ignore the possible case <strong>of</strong> repeat migration.<br />

12


thereby blurr<strong>in</strong>g differences <strong>in</strong> women’s economic activity between the countries. While the<br />

host-country FLFP rate may reflect the economic, <strong>in</strong>stitutional, <strong>and</strong> cultural environment<br />

<strong>of</strong> the immigrant, only the cultural component is reflected <strong>in</strong> the source-country FLFP rate.<br />

<strong>The</strong> estimated effect <strong>of</strong> the latter on female immigrant labor supply therefore provides<br />

<strong>in</strong>sights <strong>in</strong>to the role <strong>of</strong> culture as opposed to <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>and</strong> purely economic factors <strong>in</strong><br />

expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the diversity <strong>of</strong> labor market outcomes between immigrants.<br />

However, as Fernández (2011) claims, parents are not the only transmitters <strong>of</strong> culture.<br />

<strong>The</strong> relationship <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>of</strong> the local environment also impact <strong>in</strong>dividual behavior.<br />

By observ<strong>in</strong>g other work<strong>in</strong>g women <strong>in</strong> the host country, female immigrants might change<br />

their attitudes <strong>and</strong> beliefs regard<strong>in</strong>g women’s role <strong>in</strong> the workplace <strong>and</strong> gradually adapt to<br />

the behavior <strong>of</strong> native women. In order to answer whether immigrant women assimilate to<br />

their labor market behavior, we construct the host-country FLFPR as reflect<strong>in</strong>g the labor<br />

force participation rate <strong>of</strong> comparable natives <strong>in</strong> the host-country. In do<strong>in</strong>g so, we estimate<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard labor force participation regressions for the sample <strong>of</strong> native women separately<br />

by host-country. 16 By allow<strong>in</strong>g the determ<strong>in</strong>ants <strong>of</strong> women’s labor supply decisions to vary<br />

over countries, we take <strong>in</strong>to account that the countries with<strong>in</strong> Europe differ with respect to<br />

their culture, <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>and</strong> economic conditions <strong>and</strong> that these differences are reflected<br />

<strong>in</strong> female labor supply decisions. After fitt<strong>in</strong>g these models, we calculate for each native<br />

women the predicted probability <strong>of</strong> participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the labor market. <strong>The</strong> average values<br />

<strong>of</strong> these predicted probabilities by different age groups <strong>and</strong> survey waves then serve as<br />

our <strong>in</strong>dicators <strong>of</strong> the host-country participation rate – F LF P R k . Stated differently, we<br />

assign each immigrant women the aggregated host-country labor force participation rate<br />

<strong>of</strong> natives surveyed <strong>in</strong> the same wave <strong>in</strong> the same age group. <strong>The</strong> differentiation by age<br />

group is important as the demographic composition <strong>of</strong> immigrants differs largely across<br />

European countries.<br />

On both the source- <strong>and</strong> the host-country level, we control for a variety <strong>of</strong> additional<br />

economic <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional <strong>in</strong>dicators that might have an impact on <strong>in</strong>dividual labor supply<br />

decisions. We <strong>in</strong>clude the country’s total fertility rate, which is assumed to be negatively<br />

correlated with a country’ FLFP rate, <strong>and</strong> its GDP per capita, an important push <strong>and</strong><br />

pull factor <strong>of</strong> immigration, respectively. On the source-country level, we further <strong>in</strong>clude a<br />

variable denot<strong>in</strong>g the average years <strong>of</strong> school<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> the population aged 15 <strong>and</strong> over <strong>in</strong> the<br />

immigrant’s home country. As shown by Borjas (1992, 1995), the level <strong>of</strong> ethnic human<br />

capital (as measured by average wages or education <strong>of</strong> the immigrant group) may help to<br />

expla<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual outcomes such as education or earn<strong>in</strong>gs due to ethnic externalities <strong>in</strong><br />

the human capital process. As Fernández <strong>and</strong> Fogli (2009) state, one way to th<strong>in</strong>k about<br />

these human capital externalities is that the human capital embodied <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>dividual’s<br />

16 <strong>The</strong> models <strong>in</strong>clude controls for age, education, marital status, number/age <strong>of</strong> the children, <strong>and</strong> year<br />

dummies. <strong>The</strong> estimation results are available from the authors upon request.<br />

13


ethnic network matters. Includ<strong>in</strong>g the school enrollment rates <strong>in</strong> the source country <strong>in</strong><br />

our analysis can therefore serve as a proxy for average parental human capital <strong>and</strong> for the<br />

human capital embodied <strong>in</strong> the woman’s ethnic network.<br />

We further <strong>in</strong>clude some additional <strong>in</strong>dicators on the host-country level. One problem<br />

<strong>in</strong> analyz<strong>in</strong>g immigrant labor supply across different countries is that these countries<br />

might differ with respect to the immigrants’ access to the labor market. Not only may<br />

third-country immigrants be prohibited to work <strong>in</strong> the country <strong>of</strong> residence <strong>in</strong> the first<br />

years after arrival, they may further have limited access to the full labor market, education<br />

system or employment services <strong>of</strong> the host country. In order to address this issue, me<br />

make use <strong>of</strong> the Migrant Integration Policy Index (MIPEX) 17 , which measures policies<br />

<strong>in</strong>tegrat<strong>in</strong>g migrants <strong>in</strong> 25 EU member states <strong>and</strong> 3 non-EU countries. It considers over<br />

140 policy <strong>in</strong>dicators grouped <strong>in</strong>to 6 broad policy areas, one <strong>of</strong> which is the “labor market<br />

access” <strong>of</strong> immigrants. “Labor market access” measures if migrant workers are eligible for<br />

the same opportunities as EU nationals to work <strong>in</strong> most sectors. In particular, it takes<br />

<strong>in</strong>to account if migrant workers can count on help from labor market <strong>in</strong>tegration measures<br />

to adjust to the language <strong>and</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>essional dem<strong>and</strong>s <strong>of</strong> the labor market. Moreover, it<br />

measures how secure migrant workers are <strong>in</strong> their employment, if they can renew most<br />

types <strong>of</strong> work permits <strong>and</strong> rema<strong>in</strong> liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the country <strong>and</strong> look for work if they lose their<br />

job. <strong>The</strong> <strong>in</strong>dex varies between 0 <strong>and</strong> 100, with higher values mean<strong>in</strong>g that migrants have<br />

more rights <strong>in</strong> the correspond<strong>in</strong>g policy area.<br />

A major concern when exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the labor market behavior <strong>of</strong> immigrants across<br />

host countries is the selection <strong>of</strong> immigrants <strong>in</strong>to these countries. Although cross-country<br />

migration decisions are clearly non-r<strong>and</strong>om, our primary concern here is whether selective<br />

migration could spuriously generate an effect <strong>of</strong> host-country FLFPR on immigrant<br />

women’s labor supply <strong>in</strong> their host country. It can be argued that female immigrants with<br />

high preferences for work<strong>in</strong>g women, who <strong>in</strong>tend to participate <strong>in</strong> the labor market <strong>in</strong> their<br />

host country, will migrate to countries that <strong>of</strong>fer the best opportunities to do so. If this is<br />

the case, a positive correlation between immigrant women’s probability <strong>of</strong> participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong><br />

the labor market <strong>and</strong> the FLFP rate <strong>in</strong> their host country may not provide clear evidence<br />

for an assimilation <strong>of</strong> immigrants towards the FLFP <strong>of</strong> natives, but might rather reflect a<br />

selection <strong>of</strong> high pre-migration labor supply women <strong>in</strong>to high FLFP host countries.<br />

In order to address this problem, we attempt to control for the immigrants’ migration<br />

decision as good as possible. In addition to <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dicators for the host country’s<br />

GDP <strong>and</strong> fertility rate, we control for the country’s unemployment rate, argu<strong>in</strong>g that<br />

women with high preferences for market work, whose migration decision is economically<br />

motivated, will migrate to countries with good employment opportunities <strong>and</strong> therefore<br />

17 MIPEX is led by the British Council <strong>and</strong> Migration Policy Group (MPG) <strong>and</strong> is freely accessible at:<br />

http://www.mipex.eu/.<br />

14


low unemployment rates.<br />

A further control variable added to capture the selection <strong>of</strong> immigrants <strong>in</strong>to host<br />

countries is the share <strong>of</strong> immigrants from the same country <strong>of</strong> ancestry liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the host<br />

country. We <strong>in</strong>clude this variable to control for the fact that immigrants from countries<br />

with less traditional gender roles may choose to move to less traditional countries, <strong>and</strong><br />

similarly, those from countries with more traditional gender roles may choose to move<br />

to more traditional countries. While this variable serves as a proxy for the immigrant’s<br />

migration decision, it might also reflect the immigrants’ composition <strong>of</strong> the neighborhood.<br />

As Fernández <strong>and</strong> Fogli (2009) argue, an <strong>in</strong>dividual’s neighborhood may play an important<br />

role <strong>in</strong> transmitt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> preserv<strong>in</strong>g a set <strong>of</strong> beliefs or preferences, <strong>in</strong>dependently <strong>of</strong> the<br />

human capital embodied <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>dividual’s ethnic network. A neighborhood that has a<br />

relatively high proportion <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividuals from the same source country may help preserve<br />

that country’s culture by punish<strong>in</strong>g behavior that is different from the norm <strong>and</strong> thereby<br />

keep the culture <strong>of</strong> the source country alive. Although the share <strong>of</strong> immigrants <strong>of</strong> the same<br />

ancestry is only a raw proxy <strong>of</strong> the immigrant’s neighborhood, it might still provide some<br />

<strong>in</strong>sights <strong>in</strong>to the role <strong>of</strong> neighborhoods <strong>in</strong> cultural transmission.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, we add some variables captur<strong>in</strong>g the relationship between the immigrant’s<br />

country <strong>of</strong> birth <strong>and</strong> her country <strong>of</strong> residence. First, we control for whether the two countries<br />

share or have ever shared a colonial relationship. This is to acknowledge the fact that<br />

countries that had the same colonial history <strong>of</strong>ten established similar <strong>in</strong>stitutional sett<strong>in</strong>gs,<br />

which not only facilitates migration flows, but also reduces the barriers <strong>of</strong> immigrants to<br />

enter the host country’s labor market.<br />

Moreover, we <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>in</strong>dicators for the geographical, l<strong>in</strong>guistic, <strong>and</strong> genetic distance<br />

between the immigrant’s source country <strong>and</strong> her host country, which serve as proxies for the<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividual costs <strong>of</strong> migration. <strong>The</strong> geographical distance is def<strong>in</strong>ed as the l<strong>in</strong>ear distance<br />

between the capitals <strong>of</strong> the source <strong>and</strong> the host country <strong>in</strong> 1,000 kilometers. <strong>The</strong> measure<br />

<strong>of</strong> the l<strong>in</strong>guistic distance between the host <strong>and</strong> the source country is drawn from l<strong>in</strong>guistic<br />

research. <strong>The</strong> so-called Automatic Similarity Judgment Program (ASJP), developed by<br />

the German Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology, automatically evaluates<br />

the phonetic similarity between all <strong>of</strong> the world’s languages. <strong>The</strong> basic idea is to compare<br />

pairs <strong>of</strong> words hav<strong>in</strong>g the same mean<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> two different languages accord<strong>in</strong>g to their<br />

pronunciation. <strong>The</strong> average similarity across a specific set <strong>of</strong> words is then taken as a<br />

measure for the l<strong>in</strong>guistic distance between the languages (Bakker et al., 2009). 18 Lastly,<br />

genetic distance is measured as the difference <strong>in</strong> allele frequencies. Alleles are the specific<br />

manifestation <strong>of</strong> a gene, which might differ between <strong>in</strong>dividuals. <strong>The</strong> genetic distance<br />

measure as def<strong>in</strong>ed by Cavalli-Sforza et al. (1994) is related to the <strong>in</strong>verse probability that<br />

18 This measure was first applied to economics by Isphord<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Otten (2011), who analyze the effect<br />

<strong>of</strong> l<strong>in</strong>guistic distance on the language fluency <strong>of</strong> immigrants <strong>in</strong> Germany.<br />

15


groups <strong>of</strong> alleles are the same for two populations. Hence, the lower the common frequency<br />

<strong>of</strong> alleles <strong>in</strong> two populations, the longer these populations have been separated. 19 Genetic<br />

distance therefore serves as a proxy for the cultural distance between two countries, which<br />

might have an impact on the immigrants’ migration decision.<br />

While geographical, l<strong>in</strong>guistic, <strong>and</strong> genetic distance, to a certa<strong>in</strong> extent, all measure<br />

the direct <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>direct costs <strong>of</strong> migration, their effect on the labor supply behavior <strong>of</strong><br />

immigrants is theoretically ambiguous. As Chiswick (1978) states, immigrants who come<br />

from a greater distance are likely to have higher labor market returns to migration than<br />

those com<strong>in</strong>g shorter distances, all else equal. Stated differently, immigrants who migrated<br />

though fac<strong>in</strong>g high costs <strong>of</strong> migration are a positively selected sample <strong>of</strong> all immigrants <strong>and</strong><br />

may therefore have a higher chance <strong>of</strong> participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the host-country’s labor market.<br />

3.4 Descriptive Statistics<br />

Table ?? shows the descriptive statistics for all variables outl<strong>in</strong>ed above separately for the<br />

sample <strong>of</strong> first- <strong>and</strong> second-generation immigrants. <strong>The</strong> source- <strong>and</strong> host-country statistics<br />

have been calculated as average values over all years, thereby ignor<strong>in</strong>g the time variation<br />

<strong>in</strong> the macro data. For the calculation <strong>of</strong> these values, source- <strong>and</strong> host-country weights<br />

have been applied, respectively, which assign each immigrant a weight for her source (host)<br />

country correspond<strong>in</strong>g to the frequency <strong>of</strong> immigrants from that source country (<strong>in</strong> that<br />

host country).<br />

[TO BE CONTINUED]<br />

3.5 Method<br />

In a first step, we estimate the follow<strong>in</strong>g model:<br />

J<br />

lfp ijk = Φ(x ′ i β + ∑ K∑<br />

δ j c s j + γ k c h k + p ′ jk λ + t′ i ϑ + ɛ ijk), (1)<br />

j=2 k=2<br />

where lfp ijk is the labor supply decision <strong>of</strong> woman i from source country j who resides<br />

<strong>in</strong> host country k. In x i , we <strong>in</strong>clude a set <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual characteristics <strong>and</strong> household<br />

characteristics as outl<strong>in</strong>ed above. ∑ δ j c s j <strong>and</strong> ∑ γ k c h k are full sets <strong>of</strong> dummy variables for<br />

the immigrant’s source <strong>and</strong> host country, respectively, while p jk is a vector <strong>of</strong> country-pair<br />

variables describ<strong>in</strong>g the economic <strong>and</strong> cultural relationship between an immigrant’s source<br />

19 Changes <strong>in</strong> genes, hence the emergence <strong>of</strong> new alleles, happen r<strong>and</strong>omly at an almost constant time.<br />

As evolutionary pressure might direct this r<strong>and</strong>om change <strong>in</strong>to certa<strong>in</strong> directions, the genetic distance<br />

measure focuses on neutral genes, which are not prone to evolutionary pressure. By focus<strong>in</strong>g on neutral<br />

changes, the genetic distance measure therefore does not expla<strong>in</strong> differences <strong>in</strong> labor supply due to superior<br />

skills or ability.<br />

16


<strong>and</strong> host country. t i is a set <strong>of</strong> dummy variables for the year <strong>of</strong> observation <strong>and</strong> ɛ ijk is the<br />

error term.<br />

Hence, we start our analysis <strong>of</strong> immigrant women’s labor supply by us<strong>in</strong>g country<br />

dummies rather than the quantitative source- <strong>and</strong> host-country variables as our cultural<br />

proxies. This has the benefit <strong>of</strong> not requir<strong>in</strong>g the relationship between culture <strong>and</strong> lfp ijk<br />

to be l<strong>in</strong>ear <strong>in</strong> the cultural proxy. Furthermore, it allows to fully capture the effects<br />

<strong>of</strong> source-country culture <strong>and</strong> host-country characteristics on immigrant women’s labor<br />

supply. <strong>The</strong>reby, this approach is also free <strong>of</strong> any potential bias associated with omitt<strong>in</strong>g<br />

important source- or host-country variables that are correlated with F LF P . However, the<br />

ma<strong>in</strong> drawback <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the woman’s country <strong>of</strong> ancestry <strong>and</strong> her resid<strong>in</strong>g country<br />

as proxy variables is that such an approach is not explicit as to why different groups<br />

<strong>of</strong> immigrants, as def<strong>in</strong>ed by their source <strong>and</strong> host country, differ <strong>in</strong> their labor market<br />

behavior.<br />

<strong>The</strong> next logical step therefore is to replace the source-country dummies – ∑ δ j c s j – by<br />

a vector <strong>of</strong> source-country characteristics – s j :<br />

K<br />

lfp ijk = Φ(x ′ i β + s′ j θ + ∑<br />

γ k c h k + p ′ jk λ + t′ i ϑ + ɛ ijk). (2)<br />

k=2<br />

Model (2) is similar to the so-called epidemiological approach used, amongst others, by<br />

Antecol (2000), Fernández et al. (2004) <strong>and</strong> Fernández (2007). This approach enables us<br />

to measure the effect <strong>of</strong> source-country FLFP on immigrant women’s labor supply <strong>in</strong> their<br />

host country, while hold<strong>in</strong>g the host-country characteristics fixed, i.e., by still <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g a<br />

set <strong>of</strong> dummies for the immigrant’s host country – ∑ γ k c h k. In do<strong>in</strong>g so, we are able to test<br />

whether the positive correlation between source-country FLFP <strong>and</strong> immigrant women’s<br />

labor supply <strong>in</strong> the U.S. holds for immigrants <strong>in</strong>to Europe as well.<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> contributions <strong>of</strong> our paper is that we are not only able to assess the<br />

effect <strong>of</strong> source-country characteristics on female immigrant labor supply, but are also able<br />

to shed some light on the role <strong>of</strong> host-country characteristics <strong>in</strong> the labor market behavior<br />

<strong>of</strong> female immigrants <strong>in</strong>to these countries. In do<strong>in</strong>g so, we estimate the follow<strong>in</strong>g model:<br />

J<br />

lfp ijk = Φ(x ′ i β + ∑<br />

δ j c s j + h ′ k π + p′ jk λ + t′ i ϑ + ɛ ijk). (3)<br />

j=2<br />

This model differs from model (1) only by <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g a vector <strong>of</strong> host-country characteristics<br />

– h k – <strong>in</strong>stead <strong>of</strong> the host country dummies – ∑ γ k c h k. This approach enables us to<br />

measure the effect <strong>of</strong> host-country FLFP on immigrant women’s labor supply, while<br />

hold<strong>in</strong>g the source-country characteristics fixed, i.e., by still <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g a set <strong>of</strong> dummies for<br />

the immigrant’s source country – ∑ δ j c s j. (3) enables us to test whether immigrant women<br />

assimilate to the labor market behavior <strong>of</strong> native women <strong>in</strong> their host country.<br />

17


While estimates <strong>of</strong> models (2) <strong>and</strong> (3) provide <strong>in</strong>sights <strong>in</strong>to the role <strong>of</strong> a given set <strong>of</strong><br />

source- <strong>and</strong> host-country characteristics, respectively, <strong>in</strong> immigrant women’s labor supply,<br />

they do not acknowledge that the <strong>in</strong>terplay between both might also affect <strong>in</strong>dividual<br />

behavior. Specifically, one could argue that the higher the cultural difference, i.e., the<br />

higher the dissimilarity <strong>in</strong> the beliefs <strong>and</strong> attitudes regard<strong>in</strong>g work<strong>in</strong>g women between<br />

an immigrant’s source <strong>and</strong> host country, the more difficult it is to adapt to the labor<br />

market behavior <strong>of</strong> natives. In order to test this hypothesis, we estimate model (1) by<br />

now additionally <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the difference <strong>in</strong> FLFP rates between the source <strong>and</strong> the host<br />

country – (F LF P R j − F LF P R k ) – which serves as our proxy for the cultural difference<br />

between the two countries:<br />

J<br />

lfp ijk = Φ(x ′ i β + ∑ K∑<br />

δ j c s j + γ k c h k + ρ(F LF P R j − F LF P R k ) + p ′ jk λ + t′ i ϑ + ɛ ijk). (4)<br />

j=2 k=2<br />

In order to consistently estimate the parameters <strong>of</strong> equations (1) to (4), we specify the<br />

probability that a certa<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual participates <strong>in</strong> the labor market by the use <strong>of</strong> a<br />

b<strong>in</strong>ary probit model, imply<strong>in</strong>g the assumption that ɛ ijk follows a normal distribution. 20 We<br />

estimate marg<strong>in</strong>al effects <strong>in</strong> all models. To address the problem <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>traclass correlation <strong>in</strong><br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard errors <strong>of</strong> immigrants with<strong>in</strong> source- <strong>and</strong> host-country groups, respectively, we<br />

cluster st<strong>and</strong>ard errors at the source-country level (Model 2) <strong>and</strong> host-country level (Model<br />

3), respectively. 21 We further use host-country population weights <strong>in</strong> all regressions, which<br />

ensure that each country is represented <strong>in</strong> proportion to its actual population size.<br />

4 Basic Results<br />

<strong>The</strong> estimation results <strong>of</strong> Model (1) for first-generation (columns 2 <strong>and</strong> 3) <strong>and</strong> secondgeneration<br />

(columns 4 <strong>and</strong> 5) immigrants are shown <strong>in</strong> Table 1. <strong>The</strong> results for the<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>and</strong> household controls are <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with previous evidence on female (immigrant)<br />

labor supply. For both first- <strong>and</strong> second-generation immigrants, labor force participation<br />

is significantly lower among older women (46 to 59) as compared to middle-aged women<br />

(36 to 45 years). A further strong predictor <strong>of</strong> the labor supply <strong>of</strong> immigrant women is<br />

their level <strong>of</strong> education, with those hav<strong>in</strong>g completed tertiary education be<strong>in</strong>g significantly<br />

more likely <strong>and</strong> those with only a primary school degree be<strong>in</strong>g significantly less likely<br />

to participate <strong>in</strong> the labor market than those with a secondary school degree. While<br />

20 Logit <strong>and</strong> l<strong>in</strong>ear probability models yielded similar results.<br />

21 While estimat<strong>in</strong>g clustered st<strong>and</strong>ard errors is the st<strong>and</strong>ard solution to address the problem <strong>of</strong> with<strong>in</strong>group<br />

error correlation, the st<strong>and</strong>ard errors obta<strong>in</strong>ed by this method might still be downward biased if the<br />

number <strong>of</strong> clusters is very small.(see,e.g., Angrist <strong>and</strong> Pischke, 2009) We therefore check the robustness <strong>of</strong><br />

our results by estimat<strong>in</strong>g a mixed effects logit model with crossed r<strong>and</strong>om effects (see Section ??).<br />

18


first-generation female immigrants liv<strong>in</strong>g together with a partner show a lower labor force<br />

participation probability as compared to s<strong>in</strong>gle women, cohabitation is uncorrelated with<br />

the labor supply <strong>of</strong> second-generation immigrants. Although we do not know whether the<br />

partner is also an immigrant <strong>and</strong> the two migrated together, the strong negative correlation<br />

for first-generation immigrants might reflect that those women who migrated together<br />

with their partner are less likely to have migrated for their own economic <strong>in</strong>terests <strong>and</strong><br />

therefore less likely to participate <strong>in</strong> the labor market as compared to s<strong>in</strong>gle women. Both<br />

the number <strong>of</strong> children liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the household <strong>and</strong> the presence <strong>of</strong> small children (aged 0<br />

to 2) is negatively correlated with female immigrant labor supply, while the latter effect is<br />

much stronger for first-generation immigrants than for second-generation immigrants.<br />

For first-generation female immigrants, labor supply is significantly lower for those<br />

who just arrived <strong>in</strong> their host country (less than 6 years ago) than for those who live<br />

<strong>in</strong> the country for more than 20 years, while those who migrated as adults do not differ<br />

from those who migrated as children. Moreover, speak<strong>in</strong>g the host country’s language at<br />

home is positively correlated with the likelihood <strong>of</strong> participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the labor market. <strong>The</strong><br />

direction <strong>of</strong> causality between language fluency <strong>and</strong> immigrant labor supply, however, is<br />

ambiguous.<br />

<strong>The</strong> bottom <strong>of</strong> Table 1 shows the results <strong>of</strong> the variables that describe the relationship<br />

between the immigrants’ country <strong>of</strong> orig<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> their host country. With controll<strong>in</strong>g for<br />

both the immigrant’s source country <strong>and</strong> her country <strong>of</strong> residence, hardly any <strong>of</strong> these<br />

variables show explanatory power <strong>in</strong> female immigrant labor supply. However, the higher<br />

the share <strong>of</strong> immigrants from the same source country <strong>in</strong> the immigrant’s country <strong>of</strong><br />

residence, the lower women’s probability <strong>of</strong> participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the labor market.<br />

Model (1) conta<strong>in</strong>s source- <strong>and</strong> host-country dummies rather than the quantitative<br />

country variables as explanatory variables. For first- <strong>and</strong> second generation immigrants,<br />

both the source-country dummies <strong>and</strong> the host-country dummies are jo<strong>in</strong>tly highly significant,<br />

reflect<strong>in</strong>g a considerable variation <strong>in</strong> labor force participation, both between<br />

immigrant women from different countries <strong>of</strong> orig<strong>in</strong>, <strong>and</strong> between immigrant women across<br />

Europe. In order to assess the relative importance <strong>of</strong> an immigrants cultural background, as<br />

measured by the source-country fixed effects, <strong>and</strong> her cultural, <strong>in</strong>stitutional <strong>and</strong> economic<br />

environment, as measured by the host-country fixed-effects, we [...]<br />

In order to ga<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>sights <strong>in</strong>to the driv<strong>in</strong>g forces beh<strong>in</strong>d the differences <strong>in</strong> labor supply<br />

between women from different countries <strong>of</strong> orig<strong>in</strong>, we re-estimated the above specification<br />

by now replac<strong>in</strong>g the source-country dummies with the respective source-country characteristics<br />

(Model (2)). As we keep the host-country characteristics fixed, this approach is<br />

similar to the epidemiological approach used <strong>in</strong> the previous literature. <strong>The</strong> estimation<br />

results for this model are shown <strong>in</strong> Table 2.<br />

<strong>The</strong> estimated marg<strong>in</strong>al effect <strong>of</strong> our variable <strong>of</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest, F LF P R j , shows a<br />

19


strong positive correlation between the FLFP rate <strong>in</strong> the immigrant’s country <strong>of</strong> orig<strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> her probability <strong>of</strong> participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the host country’s labor market. This result holds<br />

for both first- <strong>and</strong> second-generation immigrants, while the magnitude <strong>of</strong> this effect is<br />

lower for the latter. On average, a 1-percentage-po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the source country’s<br />

FLFP rate <strong>in</strong>creases the likelihood <strong>of</strong> participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the labor market <strong>of</strong> the host country<br />

by 0.3 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts for first-generation immigrant women <strong>and</strong> ? percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts<br />

for second-generation immigrant women.<br />

In order to illustrate the magnitude <strong>of</strong> these effects, we can compare the LFP probability<br />

<strong>of</strong> women from a country with a relatively high FLFP rate, at the 75th percentile <strong>of</strong><br />

our sample, with a women from a country with a relatively low FLFP rate, at the 25th<br />

percentile. Regard<strong>in</strong>g first generation immigrants, the 25th percentile <strong>of</strong> the FLFP rate <strong>in</strong><br />

our sample is ?, which equals the FLFP rate <strong>of</strong> country? <strong>in</strong> year? <strong>and</strong> the 75th percentile<br />

is ? (country? year?). <strong>The</strong> results suggest that an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the source-country’s FLFP<br />

rate from the 25th to the 75th percentile <strong>in</strong>creases the labor force participation <strong>of</strong> firstgeneration<br />

female immigrants by approximately ? percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts. For second-generation<br />

immigrants, an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the source-country FLFP rate from the 25th percentile (country?<br />

year?) to the 75th percentile (country? year?) <strong>in</strong>creases the likelihood <strong>of</strong> participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong><br />

the labor market by approximately ? percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts.<br />

<strong>The</strong> results further show that hardly any other <strong>of</strong> the source-country characteristics<br />

has a significant impact on immigrant women’s labor supply. Lastly, we see that the<br />

effects <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>and</strong> household controls on female immigrant labor supply are<br />

robust to the substitution <strong>of</strong> the source-country dummies by the respective source-country<br />

characteristics. This <strong>in</strong>dicates that our estimates do not suffer from unobserved sourcecountry<br />

characteristics that are correlated with the <strong>in</strong>dividual determ<strong>in</strong>ants <strong>of</strong> labor<br />

supply.<br />

While our f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> a significant positive relationship between an immigrant woman’s<br />

labor supply <strong>in</strong> her country <strong>of</strong> residence <strong>and</strong> the FLFP rate <strong>in</strong> her source country supports<br />

the results <strong>of</strong> earlier studies for the U.S., little is known about the role <strong>of</strong> host-country<br />

characteristics <strong>in</strong> immigrants labor supply. In order to ga<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>sights <strong>in</strong>to whether immigrant<br />

women’s labor supply is affected by the FLFP rate <strong>in</strong> their host country, we re-estimated<br />

Model 1 by now replac<strong>in</strong>g the host-country dummies with the respective host-country<br />

characteristics (Model (3)). <strong>The</strong> estimation results for this model are shown <strong>in</strong> Table 3.<br />

For both first- <strong>and</strong> second generation immigrants, the estimated effect <strong>of</strong> F LF P R k ,<br />

the predicted labor force participation rate <strong>of</strong> native women <strong>in</strong> the same age group, is<br />

positive <strong>and</strong> significant, suggest<strong>in</strong>g a positive relationship between the FLFP rate <strong>in</strong> the<br />

immigrant’s host country <strong>and</strong> her probability <strong>of</strong> participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the labor market. [...]<br />

20


5 Robustness Checks<br />

5.1 Control for partner characteristics<br />

As outl<strong>in</strong>ed above, for women liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> couple households, labor supply decisions might<br />

be related to the characteristics <strong>of</strong> their partner for reasons related to assortative mat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>and</strong> jo<strong>in</strong>t labor supply decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g with<strong>in</strong> the household. In order to test whether<br />

our results are robust to controll<strong>in</strong>g for the characteristics <strong>of</strong> a womans’s partner, we<br />

re-estimate (2) <strong>and</strong> (3) by now <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the partner’s work<strong>in</strong>g hours <strong>and</strong> his highest level<br />

<strong>of</strong> education as additional control variables. <strong>The</strong> estimation results are displayed <strong>in</strong> Table<br />

4.<br />

For second-generation female immigrants, husb<strong>and</strong>’s work<strong>in</strong>g hours are positively<br />

correlated with their probability <strong>of</strong> participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the labor market, which might be<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicative <strong>of</strong> assortative mat<strong>in</strong>g with respect to similar preferences for market work.<br />

For first-generation immigrants, however, none such relationship is found. A possible<br />

explanation <strong>of</strong> this result is raised by the family migration model proposed by Baker<br />

<strong>and</strong> Benjam<strong>in</strong> (1997), which predicts that immigrant women will <strong>in</strong>itially take dead-end<br />

jobs to f<strong>in</strong>ance their husb<strong>and</strong>s’ human capital <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>and</strong> eventually drop out <strong>of</strong><br />

the labor market or reduce their labor supply as their husb<strong>and</strong>s’ labor market outcomes<br />

improve. <strong>The</strong> existence <strong>of</strong> a such substitutionary relationship between husb<strong>and</strong>’s <strong>and</strong><br />

wife’s labor supply might blur the positive correlation <strong>in</strong> the partner’s labor supply found<br />

for second-generation immigrants.<br />

5.2 Control for parents’ human capital <strong>and</strong> employment<br />

As outl<strong>in</strong>ed above, evidence suggests that <strong>in</strong>dividual beliefs, preferences <strong>and</strong> attitudes<br />

are transmitted from parents to children, <strong>and</strong> that this <strong>in</strong>tergenerational transmission<br />

shapes the child’s economic outcomes (see, e.g., Guiso et al., 2006; Fernández et al., 2004;<br />

Fernández <strong>and</strong> Fogli, 2009). In particular, Johnston et al. (2012) f<strong>in</strong>d a strong correlation<br />

between mothers’ <strong>and</strong> children’s gender role attitudes <strong>and</strong> that a mother’s attitudes are<br />

strongly predictive <strong>of</strong> their daughters’ labor supply. However, the authors further show<br />

that even when controll<strong>in</strong>g for the mother’s attitudes toward gender roles, her full-time<br />

employment status when her daughter was 5 years old has additional explanatory power<br />

<strong>in</strong> her daughter’s labor supply, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that both parental attitudes <strong>and</strong> the parents’<br />

actual behavior predict their children’s future labor supply decisions. In this respect, it is<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest to test whether the positive effect <strong>of</strong> source-country culture on immigrant labor<br />

supply still holds after controll<strong>in</strong>g for the labor supply <strong>of</strong> the immigrant’s parents.<br />

Controll<strong>in</strong>g for parental economic outcomes has the further advantage <strong>of</strong> disentangl<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the effect <strong>of</strong> source-country culture from that <strong>of</strong> the immigrants’ own labor supply before<br />

21


migrat<strong>in</strong>g. For first-generation immigrants, work experience prior to their arrival <strong>in</strong> the<br />

host country might be positively correlated with the source-country’s FLFPR. If this is<br />

true, than the estimated effect <strong>of</strong> the latter does not only reflect the role <strong>of</strong> source-country<br />

culture, but partly conta<strong>in</strong>s the effect <strong>of</strong> the level <strong>of</strong> job-related human capital accumulated<br />

before migration. Hav<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation on the human capital <strong>and</strong> labor supply <strong>of</strong> the<br />

immigrant’s parents can help to solve this problem, as parental economic behavior <strong>in</strong> the<br />

source country may serve as a proxy for the child’s labor supply before migrat<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

<strong>The</strong> estimation results <strong>of</strong> models (2) <strong>and</strong> (3) <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g controls for the parents’ highest<br />

level <strong>of</strong> education <strong>and</strong> their labor market status when their daughter was 14 years are<br />

displayed <strong>in</strong> Table 5.<br />

5.3 Ratio <strong>of</strong> FLFP rate to MLFP rate as a proxy for sourcecountry<br />

culture<br />

A possible concern when attempt<strong>in</strong>g to assess the effect <strong>of</strong> source-country culture on female<br />

immigrant labor supply is that such an approach might suffer from an omitted variable<br />

bias. If there exist any unobserved economic conditions <strong>in</strong> the source country (beyond<br />

the macro <strong>in</strong>dicators we controlled for) that affect an immigrant woman’s labor supply<br />

decisions, <strong>and</strong> if these factors are further correlated with the source-country FLFP rate,<br />

then the estimated effect <strong>of</strong> our cultural proxy will be biased, as it conta<strong>in</strong>s the effect <strong>of</strong><br />

these unobserved conditions as well. Although it is hard to th<strong>in</strong>k <strong>of</strong> any macroeconomic<br />

conditions that fulfill both conditions, we attempt to rule out the possibility <strong>of</strong> the existence<br />

<strong>of</strong> an omitted variable bias by check<strong>in</strong>g the robustness <strong>of</strong> our cultural proxy. Follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Blau <strong>and</strong> Kahn (2011) <strong>and</strong> Blau et al. (2011), we use the LFP rate <strong>of</strong> women relative to<br />

men’s (i.e., FLFP rate/MLFP rate) <strong>in</strong>stead <strong>of</strong> the FLFP rate as our cultural proxy. This<br />

relative measure is appropriate <strong>in</strong> that it captures the gender division <strong>of</strong> labor explicitly.<br />

If there exist any unobserved macroeconomic conditions correlated with a country’s LFP<br />

rate, these factors must differently affect the LFP rate <strong>of</strong> men <strong>and</strong> women <strong>in</strong> order to<br />

still bias our estimates. A further advantage <strong>of</strong> us<strong>in</strong>g the ratio <strong>of</strong> FLFP to MLFP is that<br />

it implicitly adjusts for problems <strong>in</strong> measur<strong>in</strong>g the labor force, particularly at different<br />

levels <strong>of</strong> economic development, at least to the extent that such problems affect men’s <strong>and</strong><br />

women’s measured participation rates similarly (Blau et al., 2011).<br />

<strong>The</strong> estimation results <strong>of</strong> model (2) us<strong>in</strong>g FLFP rate/MLFP rate as our cultural proxy<br />

are displayed <strong>in</strong> Table ??.<br />

22


6 Conclusion<br />

In the present paper, we focus on an important aspect <strong>of</strong> migration <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>tegration policy:<br />

the labor supply <strong>of</strong> first- <strong>and</strong> second-generation female immigrants. In particular, we<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestigate the extent to which home- <strong>and</strong> host-country characteristics affect immigrant<br />

woman’s labor supply <strong>in</strong> Europe to provide new evidence on the role <strong>and</strong> strength <strong>of</strong><br />

source-country culture <strong>and</strong> host-country conditions on immigrants’ labor market behavior.<br />

As the share <strong>of</strong> the population that was born abroad rises <strong>and</strong> the native-born work<strong>in</strong>gage<br />

population decl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong> many European countries, issues regard<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>tegration <strong>of</strong><br />

immigrants <strong>and</strong>, <strong>in</strong> particular, the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the LFP <strong>of</strong> female immigrants, capture<br />

attention by researchers <strong>and</strong> policymakers. In this context, knowledge about whether <strong>and</strong><br />

to what extend immigrant woman’s labor supply is shaped by the <strong>in</strong>dividual’s cultural<br />

background on the one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>stitutional framework <strong>in</strong> the host country on the<br />

other h<strong>and</strong>, is <strong>of</strong> important <strong>in</strong>terest.<br />

Us<strong>in</strong>g data from the European Social Survey 2002-2010, cover<strong>in</strong>g immigrants <strong>in</strong> 24<br />

European countries, we f<strong>in</strong>d that immigrant women’s labor supply <strong>in</strong> their host country<br />

is positively associated with the labor force participation rate <strong>in</strong> their source country.<br />

This result is consistent with previous evidence for the U.S. <strong>and</strong> suggests that immigrant<br />

women’s labor supply is affected by preferences <strong>and</strong> beliefs regard<strong>in</strong>g women’s roles <strong>in</strong><br />

her source country. <strong>The</strong> effect <strong>of</strong> this cultural proxy on the labor supply <strong>of</strong> immigrant<br />

women is robust to controll<strong>in</strong>g for spousal characteristics, parental characteristics, <strong>and</strong> a<br />

variety <strong>of</strong> source-country characteristics. Moreover, we f<strong>in</strong>d evidence for an impact <strong>of</strong> the<br />

host-country labor force participation rate <strong>of</strong> native women on female immigrant labor<br />

supply, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that immigrant women assimilate to the work behavior <strong>of</strong> natives.<br />

Policymakers <strong>in</strong> Europe as well <strong>in</strong> other immigration countries aim to <strong>in</strong>crease immigrant<br />

women’s LFP to reduce the cost <strong>of</strong> the social security system <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>crease tax revenue Due<br />

to the ag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> the native population <strong>in</strong> many European countries, issues on the f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>and</strong> the fiscal susta<strong>in</strong>ability <strong>of</strong> the welfare state capture <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g attention. A stable<br />

<strong>and</strong> grow<strong>in</strong>g source <strong>of</strong> tax revenue is crucial for the ability <strong>of</strong> welfare states to exist <strong>and</strong><br />

achieve its responsibilities.<br />

Evidence on the <strong>in</strong>terplay <strong>of</strong> dest<strong>in</strong>ation- <strong>and</strong> source-country characteristics on the LFP<br />

<strong>of</strong> immigrants might yield important <strong>in</strong>formation about the impact <strong>of</strong> different immigration<br />

policies on the labor market behavior <strong>of</strong> female immigrants. <strong>The</strong>refore, the results should<br />

be considered for policy design <strong>in</strong> Europe. Moreover, national immigration policies have a<br />

direct effect on the distribution <strong>of</strong> countries from which immigrants arrive <strong>and</strong> thereby on<br />

their cultural background (Blau <strong>and</strong> Kahn, 2011).<br />

In recent years, economists have begun to exam<strong>in</strong>e the relationship between culture <strong>and</strong><br />

economic outcomes. We document <strong>in</strong> this paper that hypotheses on the impact <strong>of</strong> culture<br />

23


<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutions on economic issues can be rigorously tested <strong>in</strong> an analytical framework.<br />

As Guiso et al. (2006) state, the <strong>in</strong>corporation <strong>of</strong> cultural elements <strong>in</strong> economic models<br />

will improve the models to capture the nuances <strong>of</strong> the real world, <strong>and</strong> make them more<br />

useful for decision makers.<br />

24


References<br />

Angrist, J. D. <strong>and</strong> Pischke, J.-S. (2009). Mostly harmless econometrics: An empiricist’s<br />

companion. Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton: Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton University Press.<br />

Antecol, H. (2000). An exam<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> cross-country differences <strong>in</strong> the gender gap <strong>in</strong><br />

labor force participation rates. Labour Economics, 7 (4), 409–426.<br />

— (2001). Why Is <strong>The</strong>re Interethnic Variation <strong>in</strong> the Gender Wage Gap? <strong>The</strong> <strong>Role</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

Cultural Factors. <strong>The</strong> Journal <strong>of</strong> Human Resources, 36 (1), 119–143.<br />

Baker, M. <strong>and</strong> Benjam<strong>in</strong>, D. (1997). <strong>The</strong> <strong>Role</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Family <strong>in</strong> Immigrants’ Labor-<br />

Market Activity: An Evaluation <strong>of</strong> Alternative Explanations. <strong>The</strong> American Economic<br />

Review, 87 (4), 705–727.<br />

Bakker, D., Müller, A., Velupillai, V., Wichmann, S., Brown, C. H., Brown,<br />

P., Egorov, D., Mailhammer, R., Grant, A. <strong>and</strong> Holman, E. W. (2009). Add<strong>in</strong>g<br />

typology to lexicostatistics: A comb<strong>in</strong>ed approach to language classification. L<strong>in</strong>guistic<br />

Typology, 13 (1).<br />

Bauer, T. K., L<strong>of</strong>strom, M. <strong>and</strong> Zimmermann, K. F. (2000). Immigration policy,<br />

assimilation <strong>of</strong> immigrants, <strong>and</strong> natives’ sentiments towards immigrants: evidence from<br />

12 OECD countries. Swedish Economic Policy Review, 7 (2), 11–53.<br />

Becker, G. S. (1965). A <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> the Allocation <strong>of</strong> Time. <strong>The</strong> Economic Journal,<br />

75 (299), 493–517.<br />

Bis<strong>in</strong>, A., Patacch<strong>in</strong>i, E., Verdier, T. <strong>and</strong> Zenou, Y. (2011). Ethnic identity <strong>and</strong><br />

labour market outcomes <strong>of</strong> immigrants <strong>in</strong> Europe. Economic Policy, 26 (65), 57–92.<br />

Black, S. E. <strong>and</strong> Devereux, P. J. (2011). Recent Developments <strong>in</strong> Intergenerational<br />

Mobility. In O. Ashenfelter <strong>and</strong> D. Card (eds.), H<strong>and</strong>book <strong>of</strong> Labor Economics, Vol. 4B,<br />

Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 1487–1541.<br />

Blau, F. D. (1992). <strong>The</strong> Fertility <strong>of</strong> Immigrant Women: Evidence from High-Fertility<br />

<strong>Source</strong> Countries. In G. J. Borjas <strong>and</strong> R. B. Freeman (eds.), Immigration <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Workforce:, Chicago: University <strong>of</strong> Chicago Press, pp. 93–134.<br />

— <strong>and</strong> Kahn, L. M. (2011). Substitution Between Individual <strong>and</strong> Cultural Capital: Pre-<br />

Migration Labor Supply, Culture <strong>and</strong> US Labor Market Outcomes Among Immigrant<br />

Women. NBER Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper No. 17275.<br />

25


—, — <strong>and</strong> Papps, K. L. (2011). Gender, <strong>Source</strong> <strong>Country</strong> <strong>Characteristics</strong>, <strong>and</strong> Labor<br />

Market Assimilation among Immigrants. Review <strong>of</strong> Economics <strong>and</strong> Statistics, 93 (1),<br />

43–58.<br />

Borjas, G. J. (1987). Self-Selection <strong>and</strong> the Earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>of</strong> Immigrants. <strong>The</strong> American<br />

Economic Review, 77 (4), 531–553.<br />

— (1992). Ethnic Capital <strong>and</strong> Intergenerational Mobility. <strong>The</strong> Quarterly Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Economics, 107 (1), 123–150.<br />

— (1995). Ethnicity, Neighborhoods, <strong>and</strong> Human-Capital Externalities. <strong>The</strong> American<br />

Economic Review, 85 (3), 365–390.<br />

Cavalli-Sforza, L. L., Menozzi, P. <strong>and</strong> Piazza, A. (1994). <strong>The</strong> history <strong>and</strong> geography<br />

<strong>of</strong> human genes. Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton N.J: Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton University Press.<br />

Chiswick, B. R. (1978). <strong>The</strong> Effect <strong>of</strong> Americanization on the Earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>of</strong> Foreign-born<br />

Men. Journal <strong>of</strong> Political Economy, 86 (5), 897–921.<br />

European Commission (2003). Treaty Concern<strong>in</strong>g the Accession <strong>of</strong> the Czech Republic,<br />

the Republic <strong>of</strong> Estonia, the Republic <strong>of</strong> Cyprus, the Republic <strong>of</strong> Latvia, the Republic<br />

<strong>of</strong> Lithuania, the Republic <strong>of</strong> Hungary, the Republic <strong>of</strong> Malta, the Republic <strong>of</strong> Pol<strong>and</strong>,<br />

the Republic <strong>of</strong> Slovenia <strong>and</strong> the Slovak Republic to thwe European Union. Official<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> the European Union L 236.<br />

European Commission (2005). Treaty Concern<strong>in</strong>g the Accession <strong>of</strong> the Republic <strong>of</strong><br />

Bulgaria <strong>and</strong> Romania to the European Union. Official Journal <strong>of</strong> the European Union<br />

L 157.<br />

European Commission (2010). Consolidated versions <strong>of</strong> the Treaty on the Function<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>of</strong> the European Union. Official Journal <strong>of</strong> the European Union C 83, Luxembourg.<br />

Luxembourg.<br />

European Commission (2011). Migrants <strong>in</strong> Europe: A statistical portrait <strong>of</strong> the first<br />

<strong>and</strong> second generation. Luxembourg: Publications Office <strong>of</strong> the European Union.<br />

Fernández, R. (2007). Alfred Marshall Lecture Women, Work, <strong>and</strong> Culture. Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

the European Economic Association, 5 (2-3), 305–332.<br />

Fernández, R. (2008). Culture <strong>and</strong> Economics. In S. N. Durlauf <strong>and</strong> L. E. Blume (eds.),<br />

<strong>The</strong> New Palgrave Dictionary <strong>of</strong> Economics, Bas<strong>in</strong>gstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp.<br />

333–340.<br />

26


Fernández, R. (2011). Does Culture Matter? In J. Benhabib, M. O. Jackson <strong>and</strong><br />

A. Bis<strong>in</strong> (eds.), H<strong>and</strong>book <strong>of</strong> Social Economics, Vol. 1A, Amsterdam: North-Holl<strong>and</strong>,<br />

pp. 481–510.<br />

Fernández, R. (2012). Cultural Change as Learn<strong>in</strong>g: <strong>The</strong> Evolution <strong>of</strong> Female Labor<br />

Force Participation over a Century. <strong>The</strong> American Economic Review (forthcom<strong>in</strong>g).<br />

Fernández, R. <strong>and</strong> Fogli, A. (2009). Culture: An Empirical Investigation <strong>of</strong> Beliefs,<br />

Work, <strong>and</strong> Fertility. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1 (1), 146–177.<br />

—, Fogli, A. <strong>and</strong> Olivetti, C. (2004). Mothers <strong>and</strong> Sons: Preference Formation<br />

<strong>and</strong> Female Labor Force Dynamics. <strong>The</strong> Quarterly Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics, 119 (4),<br />

1249–1299.<br />

Fogli, A. <strong>and</strong> Veldkamp, L. (2011). Nature or Nurture? Learn<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> the Geography<br />

<strong>of</strong> Female Labor Force Participation. Econometrica, 79 (4), 1103–1138.<br />

Gronau, R. (1977). Leisure, Home Production, <strong>and</strong> Work–the <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> the Allocation<br />

<strong>of</strong> Time Revisited. Journal <strong>of</strong> Political Economy, 85 (6), 1099–1123.<br />

Guiso, L., Sapienza, P. <strong>and</strong> Z<strong>in</strong>gales, L. (2006). Does Culture Affect Economic<br />

Outcomes? Journal <strong>of</strong> Economic Perspectives, 20 (2), 23–48.<br />

Isphord<strong>in</strong>g, I. E. <strong>and</strong> Otten, S. (2011). L<strong>in</strong>guistic Distance <strong>and</strong> the Language Fluency<br />

<strong>of</strong> Immigrants. Ruhr Economic Papers #274.<br />

Johnston, D. W., Schurer, S. <strong>and</strong> Shields, M. A. (2012). Maternal Gender <strong>Role</strong><br />

Attitudes, Human Capital Investment, <strong>and</strong> Labour Supply <strong>of</strong> Sons <strong>and</strong> Daughters. IZA<br />

Discussion Paper No. 6656.<br />

Kok, S., Bosch, N., Deelen, A. <strong>and</strong> Euwals, R. (2011). Migrant Women on the<br />

Labour Market: On the <strong>Role</strong> <strong>of</strong> Home-<strong>and</strong> <strong>Host</strong>-<strong>Country</strong> Participation. IZA Discussion<br />

Paper No. 5817.<br />

Manser, M. <strong>and</strong> Brown, M. (1980). Marriage <strong>and</strong> Household Decision-Mak<strong>in</strong>g: A<br />

Barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Analysis. International Economic Review, 21 (1), 31–44.<br />

McElroy, M. B. <strong>and</strong> Horney, M. J. (1981). Nash-Barga<strong>in</strong>ed Household Decisions:<br />

Toward a Generalization <strong>of</strong> the <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> Dem<strong>and</strong>. International Economic Review,<br />

22 (2), 333–349.<br />

Pencavel, J. (1998). Assortative Mat<strong>in</strong>g by School<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> the Work Behavior <strong>of</strong> Wives<br />

<strong>and</strong> Husb<strong>and</strong>s. <strong>The</strong> American Economic Review: Papers <strong>and</strong> Proceed<strong>in</strong>gs, 88 (2),<br />

326–329.<br />

27


Reimers, C. W. (1985). Cultural Differences <strong>in</strong> Labor Force Participation Among Married<br />

Women. <strong>The</strong> American Economic Review, 75 (2), 251–255.<br />

28


Figures<br />

Figure 1: Female Labor Force Participation Rate (Age 15-64) – Year 2011<br />

<strong>Source</strong>: ILO<br />

29


Average Marg<strong>in</strong>al Effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>Source</strong>-<strong>Country</strong> FLFPR<br />

Effect on Pr (Labor force participation)<br />

-.01 0 .01 .02<br />

With<strong>in</strong> last year<br />

1-5 years ago<br />

6-10 years ago<br />

Years s<strong>in</strong>ce migration<br />

More than 20 years ago<br />

11-20 years ago<br />

Figure 2: Effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>Source</strong>-<strong>Country</strong> FLFPR by Years s<strong>in</strong>ce Migration<br />

Average Marg<strong>in</strong>al Effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>Host</strong>-<strong>Country</strong> FLFPR<br />

Effect on Pr (Labor force participation)<br />

-.02 -.01 0 .01<br />

With<strong>in</strong> last year<br />

1-5 years ago<br />

6-10 years ago<br />

Years s<strong>in</strong>ce migration<br />

More than 20 years ago<br />

11-20 years ago<br />

Figure 3: Effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>Host</strong>-<strong>Country</strong> FLFPR by Years s<strong>in</strong>ce Migration<br />

30


Tables<br />

Table 1: Model 1 – <strong>Source</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Host</strong> <strong>Country</strong> Fixed Effects<br />

1 st -Generation 2 nd -Generation<br />

Immigrants<br />

Immigrants<br />

ME StdE ME StdE<br />

Age group (Ref.: Age 36-45)<br />

Age 26-35 −0.068 ∗ (0.037) 0.005 (0.044)<br />

Age 46-59 −0.125 † (0.038) −0.113 ∗∗∗ (0.042)<br />

Highest level <strong>of</strong> education (Ref.: Secd. education)<br />

Primary eduction −0.147 † (0.036) −0.098 ∗∗ (0.045)<br />

Tertiary education 0.076 ∗∗ (0.032) 0.098 ∗∗∗ (0.035)<br />

Partner <strong>in</strong> household −0.146 † (0.028) 0.016 (0.035)<br />

No. <strong>of</strong> children <strong>in</strong> household −0.054 ∗∗∗ (0.020) −0.087 † (0.021)<br />

Youngest child 0-2 −0.199 † (0.058) −0.128 ∗ (0.071)<br />

Youngest child 3-5 −0.060 (0.056) −0.114 ∗ (0.068)<br />

Years s<strong>in</strong>ce migration (Ref.: > 20 years)<br />

Less than 1 year −0.187 ∗ (0.104) – –<br />

1 to 5 years −0.150 ∗∗∗ (0.054) – –<br />

6 to 10 years −0.045 (0.047) – –<br />

11 to 20 years −0.002 (0.038) – –<br />

Migrated after age 18 −0.043 (0.044) – –<br />

Speaks host-country language 0.083 ∗∗ (0.039) – –<br />

Free movement <strong>of</strong> workers −0.006 (0.081) – –<br />

Relationship between source <strong>and</strong> host country<br />

Same source-country migrants (<strong>in</strong> %) −0.032 ∗∗ (0.016) −0.020 (0.021)<br />

Colonial ties 0.090 ∗ (0.054) 0.089 (0.064)<br />

Geographic distance 0.010 (0.030) 0.002 (0.059)<br />

Genetic distance 0.110 (0.188) −0.473 (0.299)<br />

L<strong>in</strong>guistic distance 0.000 (0.001) 0.002 (0.001)<br />

<strong>Host</strong>-country FE yes yes<br />

<strong>Source</strong>-country FE yes yes<br />

Year dummies yes yes<br />

Log likelihood -1616.8 -1028.9<br />

Pseudo R 2 0.148 0.095<br />

Observations 3869 2299<br />

Notes: – Robust st<strong>and</strong>ard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses. – † p < 0.001; ∗∗∗ p < 0.01; ∗∗ p < 0.05; ∗ p < 0.1. – <strong>Host</strong>-country<br />

population weights are applied.<br />

31


Table 2: Model 2 – <strong>Source</strong>-<strong>Country</strong> <strong>Characteristics</strong><br />

1 st -Generation 2 nd -Generation<br />

Immigrants<br />

Immigrants<br />

ME StdE ME StdE<br />

Age group (Ref.: Age 36-45)<br />

Age 26-35 −0.057 (0.049) 0.001 (0.036)<br />

Age 46-59 −0.116 † (0.032) −0.115 † (0.029)<br />

Highest level <strong>of</strong> education (Ref.: Secd. education)<br />

Primary eduction −0.138 † (0.033) −0.104 ∗ (0.057)<br />

Tertiary education 0.065 ∗ (0.036) 0.100 ∗∗ (0.043)<br />

Partner <strong>in</strong> household −0.133 † (0.032) 0.017 (0.029)<br />

No. <strong>of</strong> children <strong>in</strong> household −0.051 ∗∗∗ (0.017) −0.087 † (0.015)<br />

Youngest child 0-2 −0.200 ∗∗∗ (0.061) −0.118 (0.073)<br />

Youngest child 3-5 −0.081 (0.057) −0.109 (0.083)<br />

Years s<strong>in</strong>ce migration (Ref.: > 20 years)<br />

Less than 1 year −0.198 ∗ (0.113) – –<br />

1 to 5 years −0.126 ∗∗ (0.059) – –<br />

6 to 10 years −0.033 (0.055) – –<br />

11 to 20 years 0.002 (0.041) – –<br />

Migrated after age 18 −0.021 (0.049) – –<br />

Speaks host-country language 0.084 ∗∗∗ (0.031) – –<br />

Free movement <strong>of</strong> workers 0.171 ∗∗∗ (0.057) – –<br />

<strong>Source</strong>-country characteristics<br />

FLFP rate 0.003 ∗∗ (0.001) 0.003 (0.002)<br />

Total fertility rate 0.033 (0.022) 0.073 (0.055)<br />

GDP per capita −0.000 ∗∗ (0.000) −0.000 ∗ (0.000)<br />

Average years <strong>of</strong> school<strong>in</strong>g 0.015 (0.013) −0.002 (0.010)<br />

Relationship between source <strong>and</strong> host country<br />

Same source-country migrants (<strong>in</strong> %) −0.029 (0.018) −0.006 (0.012)<br />

Colonial ties 0.036 (0.040) 0.067 ∗∗ (0.032)<br />

Geographic distance 0.006 (0.009) 0.003 (0.011)<br />

Genetic distance 0.053 (0.044) −0.180 † (0.053)<br />

L<strong>in</strong>guistic distance −0.000 (0.001) 0.001 (0.001)<br />

Log likelihood -1678.1 -1042.1<br />

Pseudo R 2 0.115 0.084<br />

Observations 3869 2301<br />

Notes: – St<strong>and</strong>ard errors are clustered at the source-country level. – † p < 0.001; ∗∗∗ p < 0.01; ∗∗ p < 0.05; ∗ p < 0.1.<br />

– <strong>Host</strong>-country population weights are applied.<br />

32


Table 3: Model 3 – <strong>Host</strong>-<strong>Country</strong> <strong>Characteristics</strong><br />

1 st -Generation 2 nd -Generation<br />

Immigrants<br />

Immigrants<br />

ME StdE ME StdE<br />

Age group (Ref.: Age 36-45)<br />

Age 26-35 −0.052 (0.055) 0.056 ∗∗∗ (0.020)<br />

Age 46-59 −0.082 † (0.021) −0.074 ∗∗ (0.034)<br />

Highest level <strong>of</strong> education (Ref.: Secd. education)<br />

Primary eduction −0.144 † (0.026) −0.091 ∗∗ (0.044)<br />

Tertiary education 0.074 † (0.018) 0.097 ∗∗∗ (0.033)<br />

Partner <strong>in</strong> household −0.149 † (0.044) 0.011 (0.031)<br />

No. <strong>of</strong> children <strong>in</strong> household −0.052 ∗ (0.029) −0.088 † (0.016)<br />

Youngest child 0-2 −0.188 ∗∗∗ (0.062) −0.123 (0.099)<br />

Youngest child 3-5 −0.060 (0.049) −0.113 ∗ (0.067)<br />

Years s<strong>in</strong>ce migration (Ref.: > 20 years)<br />

Less than 1 year −0.173 (0.118) – –<br />

1 to 5 years −0.121 † (0.035) – –<br />

6 to 10 years −0.036 (0.035) – –<br />

11 to 20 years 0.003 (0.019) – –<br />

Migrated after age 18 −0.046 (0.054) – –<br />

Speaks host-country language 0.054 ∗ (0.032) – –<br />

Free movement <strong>of</strong> workers 0.013 (0.068) – –<br />

<strong>Host</strong>-country characteristics<br />

FLFP rate 0.007 † (0.001) 0.008 † (0.002)<br />

Total fertility rate −0.201 † (0.035) −0.082 ∗ (0.046)<br />

GDP per capita −0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000)<br />

Unemployment rate −0.003 (0.006) −0.009 ∗ (0.004)<br />

MIPEX: Labor market access 0.001 (0.001) – –<br />

Relationship between source <strong>and</strong> host country<br />

Same source-country migrants (<strong>in</strong> %) −0.020 (0.013) −0.012 (0.011)<br />

Colonial ties 0.055 ∗ (0.032) 0.062 (0.038)<br />

Geographic distance 0.035 (0.032) −0.023 (0.030)<br />

Genetic distance −0.030 (0.061) −0.129 † (0.037)<br />

L<strong>in</strong>guistic distance −0.000 (0.001) 0.001 ∗∗∗ (0.000)<br />

Log likelihood -1620.3 -1029.7<br />

Pseudo R 2 0.146 0.094<br />

Observations 3869 2299<br />

Notes: – St<strong>and</strong>ard errors are clustered at the source-country level. – † p < 0.001; ∗∗∗ p < 0.01; ∗∗ p < 0.05; ∗ p < 0.1.<br />

– <strong>Host</strong>-country population weights are applied.<br />

33


Table 4: Models 2 & 3 – Controll<strong>in</strong>g for Partner <strong>Characteristics</strong><br />

Model 2 Model 3<br />

1 st -Generation 2 nd -Generation 1 st -Generation 2 nd -Generation<br />

Immigrants Immigrants Immigrants Immigrants<br />

Partner characteristics<br />

Work<strong>in</strong>g hours −0.000 0.002 ∗∗ −0.000 0.002 †<br />

(0.001) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

Education (Ref.: Secd. education)<br />

Primary eduction −0.006 0.011 0.009 0.005<br />

(0.039) (0.048) (0.027) (0.022)<br />

Tertiary education 0.021 −0.003 0.022 −0.000<br />

(0.031) (0.026) (0.021) (0.021)<br />

Other education −0.026 −0.069 0.017 0.109 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.107) (0.130) (0.055) (0.042)<br />

FLFP rate 0.003 ∗∗ 0.003 0.007 † 0.008 †<br />

(0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002)<br />

Individual controls yes yes yes yes<br />

<strong>Host</strong>-country FE yes yes no no<br />

<strong>Source</strong>-country FE no no yes yes<br />

Relationship variables yes yes yes yes<br />

Year dummies yes yes yes yes<br />

Log likelihood -1609.1 -1010.0 -1549.9 -998.5<br />

Pseudo R 2 0.108 0.091 0.141 0.100<br />

Observations 3683 2209 3683 2207<br />

Notes: – Marg<strong>in</strong>al effects with clustered st<strong>and</strong>ard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses. – † p < 0.001; ∗∗∗ p < 0.01;<br />

∗∗ p < 0.05; ∗ p < 0.1. – <strong>Host</strong>-country population weights are applied. – Model 2 further <strong>in</strong>cludes the<br />

same source-country characteristics as shown <strong>in</strong> Table 2. – Model 3 further <strong>in</strong>cludes the same host-country<br />

characteristics as shown <strong>in</strong> Table 3.<br />

34


Table 5: Models 2 & 3 – Controll<strong>in</strong>g for Parents’ <strong>Characteristics</strong><br />

Model 2 Model 3<br />

1 st -Generation 2 nd -Generation 1 st -Generation 2 nd -Generation<br />

Immigrants Immigrants Immigrants Immigrants<br />

Controll<strong>in</strong>g for father characteristics<br />

Father employed at age 14 0.056 0.092 0.076 ∗∗ 0.099 ∗∗<br />

(0.055) (0.061) (0.030) (0.049)<br />

Father’s education (Ref.: Secd. education)<br />

Primary eduction 0.055 ∗ 0.091 ∗∗∗ 0.064 ∗∗ 0.099 †<br />

(0.032) (0.034) (0.030) (0.028)<br />

Tertiary education 0.061 0.124 ∗∗∗ 0.069 ∗∗ 0.121 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.042) (0.040) (0.030) (0.043)<br />

Other education 0.031 −0.053 0.024 0.139 †<br />

(0.094) (0.155) (0.057) (0.038)<br />

FLFP rate 0.003 ∗∗ 0.002 0.007 † 0.009 †<br />

(0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002)<br />

Individual controls yes yes yes yes<br />

<strong>Host</strong>-country FE yes yes no no<br />

<strong>Source</strong>-country FE no no yes yes<br />

Relationship variables yes yes yes yes<br />

Year dummies yes yes yes yes<br />

Log likelihood -1486.5 -879.1 -1422.7 -862.2<br />

Pseudo R 2 0.111 0.103 0.150 0.119<br />

Observations 3475 2042 3475 2040<br />

Controll<strong>in</strong>g for mother characteristics<br />

Mother employed at age 14 0.041 0.078 ∗ 0.029 ∗ 0.085 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.026) (0.043) (0.018) (0.032)<br />

Mother’s education (Ref.: Secd. education)<br />

Primary eduction 0.074 ∗∗ −0.052 0.077 ∗∗∗ −0.048<br />

(0.033) (0.045) (0.024) (0.034)<br />

Tertiary education −0.004 −0.056 0.002 −0.071 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.048) (0.065) (0.028) (0.026)<br />

Other education 0.090 −0.165 0.084 −0.008<br />

(0.086) (0.135) (0.082) (0.043)<br />

FLFP rate 0.004 ∗∗∗ 0.003 ∗ 0.007 † 0.007 †<br />

(0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001)<br />

Individual controls yes yes yes yes<br />

<strong>Host</strong>-country FE yes yes no no<br />

<strong>Source</strong>-country FE no no yes yes<br />

Relationship variables yes yes yes yes<br />

Year dummies yes yes yes yes<br />

Log likelihood -1440.4 -835.7 -1379.5 -820.0<br />

Pseudo R 2 0.117 0.109 0.155 0.125<br />

Observations 3407 1991 3407 1989<br />

Notes: – Marg<strong>in</strong>al effects with clustered st<strong>and</strong>ard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses. – † p < 0.001; ∗∗∗ p < 0.01; ∗∗ p < 0.05;<br />

∗ p < 0.1. – <strong>Host</strong>-country population weights are applied. – Model 2 further <strong>in</strong>cludes the same source-country<br />

characteristics as shown <strong>in</strong> Table 2. – Model 3 further <strong>in</strong>cludes the same host-country characteristics as shown <strong>in</strong><br />

Table 3<br />

35


Appendix<br />

36


Table A1: Macro Data – <strong>Source</strong>s <strong>and</strong> Descriptions [HINWEIS: GILT NUR ALS VORLAGE, DATENQUELLEN<br />

MÜSSEN ENTSPRECHEND ANGEPASST WERDEN!]<br />

Variable <strong>Source</strong> Year Description<br />

Population under age 15 ? 2002 Population under age 15 as percentage <strong>of</strong> total population<br />

Population age 65 <strong>and</strong> above ? 2002 Population age 65 <strong>and</strong> above as percentage <strong>of</strong> total population<br />

Unemployment rate Eurostat 2002 <strong>and</strong> 2003 Unemployment rate for <strong>in</strong>dividuals aged 15 <strong>and</strong> above<br />

Female labor force participation Eurostat 2002 <strong>and</strong> 2003 Employment rate <strong>of</strong> women aged 15 <strong>and</strong> above<br />

GDP Eurostat 2002 <strong>and</strong> 2003 Purchas<strong>in</strong>g Power St<strong>and</strong>ard <strong>of</strong> GDP per <strong>in</strong>habitant <strong>in</strong> percentage <strong>of</strong> the EU average<br />

Income <strong>in</strong>equality Eurostat 2002 <strong>and</strong> 2003 Inequality <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come distribution (80/20 qu<strong>in</strong>tile ratio), i.e. the ratio <strong>of</strong> total <strong>in</strong>come<br />

received by the 20% <strong>of</strong> the population with the highest <strong>in</strong>come (top qu<strong>in</strong>tile) to that<br />

received by the 20% <strong>of</strong> the population with the lowest <strong>in</strong>come (lowest qu<strong>in</strong>tile)<br />

Social expenditure Eurostat 2002 <strong>and</strong> 2003 Purchas<strong>in</strong>g Power St<strong>and</strong>ard <strong>of</strong> social expenditure per head <strong>of</strong> population<br />

% secondary education Eurostat 2002 <strong>and</strong> 2003 Percentage <strong>of</strong> total population aged 25 to 64 hav<strong>in</strong>g completed at least upper<br />

secondary education<br />

Formal childcare Eurostat 2005 Average number <strong>of</strong> weekly hours <strong>of</strong> formal care <strong>of</strong> children children 0-3 years<br />

Years s<strong>in</strong>ce democracy Database <strong>of</strong> Political Institutions 2010 –<br />

World Bank (?)<br />

2002 <strong>and</strong> 2003 Years s<strong>in</strong>ce the country has been democratic<br />

Orientation <strong>of</strong> government Database <strong>of</strong> Political Institutions 2010 –<br />

World Bank<br />

2003 Party orientation with respect to economic policy. Dist<strong>in</strong>guishes between Right, Left<br />

or Center; Right: Conservative, Christian democratic, or right-w<strong>in</strong>g. Left:<br />

Communist, socialist, social democratic, or left-w<strong>in</strong>g. Center: centrist. S<strong>in</strong>ce data<br />

refer to the 1st January <strong>of</strong> each year, data for 2003 are also used for people be<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>terviewed <strong>in</strong> the end <strong>of</strong> 2002.<br />

Tax deductibility <strong>of</strong> donations European Foundation Center (2011) &<br />

Giv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Europe – European<br />

Cross-Boarder Giv<strong>in</strong>g Database<br />

2003-2010<br />

2003 Percentage <strong>of</strong> amount deductible <strong>in</strong> case <strong>of</strong> a donation <strong>of</strong> 1 e0,000. Ranges from 0<br />

(non-deductible) to 1 (fully deductible).<br />

Personal <strong>in</strong>come tax rate ? 2005 Average personal <strong>in</strong>come tax rates<br />

Corruption Index (0-10) Transparency International 2003 Recode <strong>of</strong> Corruption Perceptions Index 2003<br />

Altruism <strong>of</strong> people (0-10) ESS, Round 1 2002/2003 Weighted country average <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual’s answer to the question: “Would you say<br />

that most <strong>of</strong> the time people try to be helpful or that they are mostly look<strong>in</strong>g out<br />

for themselves? Please <strong>in</strong>dicate on a scale from 0 (People mostly look out for<br />

themselves) to 10 (People mostly try to be helpful).”<br />

% belong<strong>in</strong>g to religion ESS, Round 1 2002/2003 Share <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividuals who consider themselves as belong<strong>in</strong>g to any particular religion<br />

or denom<strong>in</strong>ation<br />

Share <strong>of</strong> protestants ESS, Round 1 2002/2003 Share <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividuals be<strong>in</strong>g protestant<br />

Satisfaction with government (0-10) ESS, Round 1 2002/2003 Weighted country average <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual’s answer to the question: “Now th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g<br />

about the [country] government, how satisfied are you with the way it is do<strong>in</strong>g its<br />

job? Please <strong>in</strong>dicate on a scale from 0 (Extremely dissatisfied) to 10 (Extremely<br />

satisfied).”<br />

37


Supplementary Appendix<br />

(not <strong>in</strong>tended for publication)<br />

i

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!