27.11.2012 Views

Lecture Notes for Finance 1 (and More).

Lecture Notes for Finance 1 (and More).

Lecture Notes for Finance 1 (and More).

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

4.2. THE SINGLE PERIOD MODEL 45<br />

Proof. Assume πc < ψ 1c1 + . . . + ψ ScS. Buy the security c <strong>and</strong> sell the<br />

portfolio θc. The price of θc is by assumption higher than πc, so we receive<br />

a positive cash-flow now. The cash-flow at time 1 is 0. Hence there is an<br />

arbitrage opportunity. If πc > ψ 1c1 + . . . + ψ ScS reverse the strategy. �<br />

Definition 22 The market is complete if <strong>for</strong> every y ∈ R S there exists a<br />

θ ∈ R N such that<br />

D ⊤ θ = y<br />

i.e. if the rows of D (the columns of D ⊤ ) span R S .<br />

Proposition 8 If the market is complete <strong>and</strong> arbitrage-free, there exists precisely<br />

one state-price vector ψ.<br />

The proof is exactly as in Chapter 3 <strong>and</strong> we are ready to price new<br />

securities in the financial market; also known as pricing of contingent claim. 2<br />

Here is how it is done in a one-period model: Construct a set of securities<br />

(the D-matrix,) <strong>and</strong> a set of prices. Make sure that (π, D) is arbitrage-free.<br />

Make sure that either<br />

(a) the model is complete, i.e. there are as many linearly independent<br />

securities as there are states<br />

or<br />

(b) the contingent claim we wish to price is redundant given (π, D).<br />

Clearly, (a) implies (b) but not vice versa. (a) is almost always what is<br />

done in practice. Given a contingent claim c = (c1, . . .,cS). Now compute<br />

the price of the contingent claim as<br />

π (c) = 1<br />

R0<br />

E q (c) ≡ 1<br />

R0<br />

S�<br />

i=1<br />

qici<br />

(4.1)<br />

where qi = ψ i<br />

d0 ≡ R0ψ i. The method in Equation (4.1) (<strong>and</strong> the generalizations<br />

of it we’ll meet in Chapters 5 <strong>and</strong> 6) is often called risk-neutral pricing.<br />

Arbitrage-free prices are calculated as discounted expected values (with some<br />

new or artificial probabilities, the q’s), ie. as if agents were risk-neutral. But<br />

the “as if” is important to note. No assumption of actual agent risk-neutrality<br />

is use to derive (4.1), just (slightly implicitly, but spelled out more in the<br />

next section) that they prefer more to less. As a catch-phrase: Risk-neutral<br />

2 A contingent claim just a r<strong>and</strong>om variable describing pay-offs; the pay-off is contingent<br />

on ω. The term (financial) derivative (asset, contract, or security) is largely synonymous,<br />

except that we are usually more specific about the pay-off being contingent on another<br />

financial asset such as a stock. We say option, we have even more specific pay-off structures<br />

in mind.<br />

complete market<br />

contingent claim<br />

risk-neutral<br />

pricing

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!