12.07.2015 Views

Ageing and welfare reform in the Nordic Countries, 1990-2010 ...

Ageing and welfare reform in the Nordic Countries, 1990-2010 ...

Ageing and welfare reform in the Nordic Countries, 1990-2010 ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

equivalent to a m<strong>and</strong>atory system by hav<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> state foot <strong>the</strong> bill– <strong>and</strong> subsequently by mak<strong>in</strong>gbenefits more generous <strong>in</strong> terms of compensation <strong>and</strong> duration. 20After 2000, this development was reversed <strong>in</strong> Denmark <strong>and</strong> Sweden by <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g members’contributions. Much of this was carried through <strong>in</strong>directly <strong>and</strong> tacitly, via reduc<strong>in</strong>g or ab<strong>and</strong>on<strong>in</strong>gtax deductions. In Sweden, members’ contributions also became dependent on unemployment risk,<strong>and</strong> benefits became far less generous. In both countries, benefits became <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly conditionalon work & mobility requirements. In Sweden 2007-08, it became impossible to reqalify for benefitsthrough activation, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> compensation rate was reduced <strong>and</strong> related to duration of benefits 21which was reduced to 300 days, with possibility of 300 more days on a reduced benefit. On thisbackground, it is hardly an exaggeration to speak of a re-commodification <strong>and</strong> a privatization ofsocial risk. “Systemic retrenchment” was also <strong>in</strong>volved as unions were weakened.In Denmark <strong>the</strong> “flexicurity” system was jeopardized by an unexpected redution of duration ofbenefits to only two years <strong>in</strong> <strong>2010</strong>. As a response, wage earners claimed more employmentprotection <strong>in</strong> collective agreements. Consider<strong>in</strong>g retrenchment elsewhere, duration of two years isnot exceptionally bad. But duration was <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> “security” component of Danish “flexicurity” –<strong>the</strong> so-called golden triangle of liberal employment protection, generous security for <strong>the</strong>unemployed, <strong>and</strong> activation to br<strong>in</strong>g people back to work (Madsen, 2002). This <strong>in</strong>stitutionalcomplementarity was nearly ab<strong>and</strong>oned over night. So far, it is difficult to guess about effects (DetØkonomiske Råd 2009a; Nørgaard 2009), but <strong>the</strong> Danish <strong>and</strong> Swedish <strong>reform</strong>s do representsignificant <strong>in</strong>stances of re-commodification, <strong>and</strong> if <strong>the</strong> economic recession cont<strong>in</strong>ues as expected, itwill have a significant social impact <strong>in</strong> both countries.Tax <strong>reform</strong>sF<strong>in</strong>ally, most countries have sought to reduce taxes on labour <strong>in</strong> order to stimulate labour marketparticipation. Whe<strong>the</strong>r it works it rema<strong>in</strong>s contested. From <strong>the</strong> <strong>1990</strong>s, a concern for globalcompetitiveness pulled <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> same direction – ma<strong>in</strong>ly aimed at reduc<strong>in</strong>g corporate taxes but alsotaxes on labour. As far as taxes on labour is concerned, empirical analyses have never been able tovalidate tax flight (Velfærdskommissionen, 2005; Pedersen, Røed & Schröder, 2003).Whereas <strong>the</strong> labour supply argument addresses marg<strong>in</strong>al taxes, migration <strong>in</strong>centives are aboutaverage taxes, <strong>and</strong> about <strong>the</strong> sum of all taxes – or ra<strong>the</strong>r: about <strong>the</strong> sum of all taxes plus”necessary” social expenditures. Consider<strong>in</strong>g that mobility across borders is found ma<strong>in</strong>ly among<strong>the</strong> young – who will have children sooner or later – <strong>the</strong> important question is how economic<strong>in</strong>centives look for this target group. With large subsidies for high-quality child care, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Nordic</strong>countries appear highly competitive <strong>in</strong> this respect: Few people <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> relevant taget group wouldhave economic <strong>in</strong>centives to emigrate from <strong>the</strong> <strong>Nordic</strong> region.As regards taxation of wages, <strong>Nordic</strong> countries are not high tax countries anymore. This holds both20 Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Roed (1999) members f<strong>in</strong>anced only some 20 per cent of <strong>the</strong> costs <strong>in</strong> Denmark, <strong>and</strong> about 5 per cent <strong>in</strong>Sweden <strong>and</strong> F<strong>in</strong>l<strong>and</strong> at that time.21 People with children under 18 ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> 70 per cent for addditional 30 weeks.16

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!