12.07.2015 Views

Switching Costs in Two-sided Markets - Ecares

Switching Costs in Two-sided Markets - Ecares

Switching Costs in Two-sided Markets - Ecares

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Similarly, a side-B consumer is <strong>in</strong>different between buy<strong>in</strong>g and not buy<strong>in</strong>g from platform1 ifv B + e B (1 − n A 0,2) − (1 − x) − p B 1,2 = 0,which can be reduced ton B 1,2 = 1 − x = v B + e B (1 − n A 0,2) − p B 1,2.We solve the game by backward <strong>in</strong>duction as before. To simplify the exposition, wefocus on the special case where e A = e B = e, µ A = 0, and δ A = δ B = δ F = δ. Considerthe symmetric equilibrium. We f<strong>in</strong>d the follow<strong>in</strong>g first-period equilibrium prices:p A 0,1 =1 + δs A3 − e2 − v B2 − 2δs2 A (3e2 − 2)3(1 − e 2 ,)p B 0,1 = v B2 .Differentiat<strong>in</strong>g p A 0,1 with respect to s A, we obta<strong>in</strong>Proposition 7. In the two-period two-<strong>sided</strong> multi-hom<strong>in</strong>g duopoly model, where oneside of the consumers multi-homes, while the other side s<strong>in</strong>gle-homes, each side exertsthe same external benefit on the other side, all consumers’ preferences are <strong>in</strong>dependentover time, and they are equally patient as the platforms,i. For the group of consumers who bear switch<strong>in</strong>g costs,• If network externality is sufficiently weak, then the first-period equilibriumprice paid by them always <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> switch<strong>in</strong>g costs.• If network externality is sufficiently strong, then the relationship between thefirst-period equilibrium price paid by them and switch<strong>in</strong>g costs is <strong>in</strong>verted U-shaped.ii. If the market is fully covered, then prices tend to be higher on the side that multihomes,and lower on the side that s<strong>in</strong>gle-homes.See Appendix E for the proof.(i) implies that strong externality makes it more likely that first-period equilibriumprices decrease <strong>in</strong> switch<strong>in</strong>g costs, which is consistent with Proposition 5. However,(ii) is different from the s<strong>in</strong>gle-hom<strong>in</strong>g model. S<strong>in</strong>ce side B multi-homes, there is nocompetition between the two platforms to attract this group. The high prices faced bythe multi-hom<strong>in</strong>g side is a consequence of each platform hav<strong>in</strong>g monopoly power overthis side, and the large revenues are used <strong>in</strong> the form of lower prices to conv<strong>in</strong>ce thes<strong>in</strong>gle-hom<strong>in</strong>g side to jo<strong>in</strong> the platform.Before, <strong>in</strong> the s<strong>in</strong>gle-hom<strong>in</strong>g model welfare analysis is not mean<strong>in</strong>gful: welfare isalways the same because all consumers buy one unit of good, the size of the two groupsis fixed, and the whole market is served. It ignores the possible demand-expansion and17

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!