02.12.2012 Views

The value of housing design and layout

The value of housing design and layout

The value of housing design and layout

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

corrosive effect on quality <strong>and</strong> resisting innovation’. <strong>The</strong>y go on to indicate that,<br />

‘while there are signs that things may be changing, these forces must currently be<br />

seen as a major constraint on the promotion <strong>of</strong> more urban <strong>housing</strong>’.<br />

A cautionary note is sounded in other research regarding the operation <strong>of</strong> the l<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>housing</strong> market under conditions <strong>of</strong> supply constraint in the UK. Cheshire <strong>and</strong><br />

Sheppard in 1997 indicated that, under conditions <strong>of</strong> sustained <strong>housing</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

l<strong>and</strong> supply constraints, it is generally ‘planning amenities’ or space that increase<br />

disproportionately in price in comparison with ‘reproducible’ attributes <strong>of</strong> <strong>housing</strong>.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se ‘goods’ which the planning system delivers are <strong>value</strong>d, the authors argue, but<br />

in ignorance <strong>of</strong> the price that is paid for those planning amenities. ‘<strong>The</strong>ir <strong>value</strong>s are<br />

not just incorporated in the price paid for a house. <strong>The</strong>re are also extra costs. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

are the higher price paid for all <strong>housing</strong> l<strong>and</strong>, shortage <strong>of</strong> space <strong>and</strong> the more<br />

cramped conditions in which we all have to live. Planning amenities are not paid for<br />

directly so they appear to be free. But because they are only produced by restricting<br />

the supply <strong>of</strong> building l<strong>and</strong>, they cause the price <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> thus <strong>of</strong> <strong>housing</strong>, to rise.’<br />

This analysis would seem to confirm <strong>and</strong> extend that <strong>of</strong> Verhage <strong>and</strong> Needham in<br />

identifying the source <strong>of</strong> the ‘extra price’ attributable to the ‘residential environment’<br />

outside the dwelling unit in the operation <strong>of</strong> a restrictive planning system. Design is<br />

not, however, one <strong>of</strong> the explicit <strong>housing</strong> attributes considered in the analysis<br />

(although access to schools <strong>and</strong> to public open space is modelled). Others also<br />

make a similar argument concerning such ‘neighbourhood externality’ effects <strong>of</strong><br />

planning-induced improvements in the quality <strong>of</strong> residential development.<br />

2.4 Housing <strong>design</strong> quality <strong>and</strong> ‘<strong>value</strong>’<br />

ADDRESSING THE GAPS<br />

<strong>The</strong> publication in 1973 <strong>of</strong> A <strong>design</strong> guide for residential areas by Essex County<br />

Council introduced a radically new framework for residential <strong>design</strong> guidance.<br />

Subsequent research into the impact <strong>of</strong> such <strong>design</strong> guidance for private residential<br />

development by the DOE/HRF in 1976 indicated a concern with the cost<br />

implications <strong>of</strong> <strong>design</strong> guidance <strong>and</strong> control. It asserted that, ‘a requirement for a<br />

more expensive <strong>design</strong> solution for the houses must be <strong>of</strong>fset by a saving in cost<br />

elsewhere, such as in road construction, or by allowing a higher density <strong>of</strong><br />

development to reduce the l<strong>and</strong> costs for each dwelling’.<br />

In a discussion paper on good <strong>design</strong> in <strong>housing</strong> by Davison in 1990, it is argued<br />

that many aspects <strong>of</strong> good <strong>design</strong> add little or no extra costs to residential<br />

schemes, but that some elements <strong>of</strong> good <strong>design</strong> do increase costs. It is argued<br />

that, ‘developers who have persisted with high <strong>design</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ards have found that<br />

their product does have an added, premium <strong>value</strong>, but only on the subsequent<br />

resale when the environment is more settled <strong>and</strong> established. This benefits<br />

discerning purchasers but does not recoup the developer’s costs’.<br />

Davison estimates that the cost <strong>of</strong> achieving a broad spectrum <strong>of</strong> <strong>design</strong><br />

improvements might be in the order <strong>of</strong> 5–10% <strong>of</strong> the l<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. He argues, ‘this<br />

seems to suggest that there should be some scope for planning intervention to<br />

redirect some <strong>of</strong> the betterment from the l<strong>and</strong>owners’ pr<strong>of</strong>its to the benefit <strong>of</strong> the<br />

T H E V A L U E O F H O U S I N G D E S I G N A N D L A Y O U T<br />

21

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!