04.01.2013 Views

Working paper template - MBA Programme der HWR Berlin

Working paper template - MBA Programme der HWR Berlin

Working paper template - MBA Programme der HWR Berlin

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Institute of Management <strong>Berlin</strong> (IMB) <strong>Working</strong> Paper No.28<br />

Fachhochschule für Wirtschaft <strong>Berlin</strong> - <strong>Berlin</strong> School of Economics<br />

empirical results, volume for freight and passengers has increased significantly, which has<br />

also resulted in improved financial performance and better productivity measures. The<br />

provision of a new rail link will increase the catchment area, adding extra demand for the<br />

airport. However, these effects will only be observed gradually in the near future.<br />

Presumably, given local demand conditions and competition from other airports, as a new<br />

equilibrium is reached even better capacity utilization will be realized. This example<br />

illustrates how measured productivity may be affected as the airport repositions itself for a<br />

new product specialization. However, we find that no adjustment has been made for such<br />

developments in typical benchmarking exercises.<br />

The other case to consi<strong>der</strong> is airport repositioning due to changes in airport or intermodal<br />

competition, leading to lower capacity utilization. The airport may have been in an equilibrium<br />

before with respect to capacity and product orientation, but such changes place it in a<br />

position where it has to adjust to the new environment. Obviously such shifts, usually not<br />

subject to management control, will lead to a drop in productivity measures even if some<br />

managers adapt a forward-looking approach to try and reach a new equilibrium.<br />

Consequently, if benchmarking is to be used in the typical disequilibrium environment, an<br />

informed debate about measures of capital and measures of capacity are needed. This<br />

implies not only looking at investment decisions, or at incremental costs, or the nature of the<br />

un<strong>der</strong>lying cost function (i.e. whether there are constant or non-constant returns to scale),<br />

but also consi<strong>der</strong>ing the lumpy nature of investment and the fact that different airport<br />

investment cycles might distort comparisons. The theory of real options would suggest that<br />

this could even lead to downward adjustment of the inputs needed to actual airport output<br />

(CAA 2000, p.27).<br />

This issue of lumpy investment points to a number of problems associated with the<br />

measurement of airport capital, especially if trying to estimate whether there are returns to<br />

scale and what form incremental costs take. Incremental costs will be influenced both by the<br />

particular physical location and the constraints imposed by previous investment. In some<br />

instances, the most cost-effective expansion will lead to the premature<br />

retirement/replacement of existing assets. In its reply to the CAA inquiry about<br />

benchmarking, Manchester Airport therefore suggests “…that the use of benchmarking in<br />

terms of comparing airport investment/capacity relationships might be inappropriate” (CAA<br />

2000).<br />

3.3. Difference in the vertical activities of airports and the associated value chain<br />

Airports differ in terms of the services supplied, some operate ground handling by<br />

themselves; others outsource this service to third parties and merely provide the core<br />

facilities at the airport and receive concession fees from those providing these services.<br />

Doganis et al (1995) and TRL have defined the following as non-core activities at airports:<br />

32

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!