15.02.2013 Views

The Effects of Location-Fixity and Local ... - List of Projects

The Effects of Location-Fixity and Local ... - List of Projects

The Effects of Location-Fixity and Local ... - List of Projects

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Location</strong>-<strong>Fixity</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>Local</strong> Embeddedness on the<br />

Value Creation <strong>of</strong> Utilities <strong>and</strong> Concession-based Firms<br />

D I S S E R T A T I O N<br />

<strong>of</strong> the University <strong>of</strong> St. Gallen,<br />

School <strong>of</strong> Management,<br />

Economics, Law, Social Sciences<br />

<strong>and</strong> International Affairs<br />

to obtain the title <strong>of</strong><br />

Doctor Oeconomiae<br />

submitted by<br />

Annette Karoline Kern-Ulmer<br />

from<br />

Austria<br />

Approved on the application <strong>of</strong><br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>. Dr. Thomas Bieger<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>. Dr. Günter Müller-Stewens<br />

Dissertation no. 3941<br />

Difo-Druck GmbH, Bamberg 2011


<strong>The</strong> University <strong>of</strong> St. Gallen, Graduate School <strong>of</strong> Business Administration,<br />

Economics, Law <strong>and</strong> Social Sciences (HSG) hereby consents to the printing <strong>of</strong> the<br />

present dissertation, without hereby expressing any opinion on the views herein<br />

expressed.<br />

St. Gallen, May 16, 2011<br />

<strong>The</strong> President:<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>. Dr. Thomas Bieger


Acknowledgements<br />

Acknowledgements<br />

<strong>The</strong> important thing in science is not so much to obtain new facts as to<br />

discover new ways <strong>of</strong> thinking about them.<br />

William Lawrence Bragg<br />

Die Inspiration zum <strong>The</strong>ma dieser Dissertation verdanke ich massgeblich einer<br />

Diskussion mit meinem Doktorvater, Pr<strong>of</strong>. Dr. Thomas Bieger, in welcher wir der<br />

Frage nachgingen, ob denn internationale Engagements von Flughafenbetreibern<br />

ökonomisch sinnvoll seien. Ebendiese <strong>The</strong>matik beschäftigte mich auch beruflich in<br />

der internationalen Geschäftsentwicklung der Flughafen Zürich AG, und damit war die<br />

Grundrichtung des <strong>The</strong>mas gefunden. Nach ersten Recherchen entst<strong>and</strong> die Idee, etwas<br />

grundsätzlicher die Expansion st<strong>and</strong>ortgebundener und infrastrukturlastiger Branchen<br />

unter dem Aspekt der ‚Value Creation‘ zu erörtern. Während der darauf folgenden<br />

intensiven Phase des Forschens, Analysierens und Schreibens waren zahlreiche<br />

Gespräche erforderlich, die für mich eine reiche Quelle an dichter und<br />

aufschlussreicher Information waren. An dieser Stelle sei allen Impulsgebern im<br />

Erstellungprozess herzlich gedankt. Ohne deren wertvolle Beiträge wäre diese Arbeit<br />

nicht möglich gewesen.<br />

Neben meinem Dank an Doktorvater Pr<strong>of</strong>. Dr. Thomas Bieger und meinen<br />

Korreferenten Pr<strong>of</strong>. Dr. Günter Müller-Stewens, die mich weise, pointiert und effizient<br />

im Forschungsprozess begleitet haben, möchte ich insbesondere Dr. des. Andreas<br />

Nemeth danken, der mich wesentlich zu diesem Dissertationsprojekt inspiriert hat.<br />

Cyrill Rüegg, Urs Brütsch und der Flughafen Zürich AG danke ich, da ich durch deren<br />

Umsicht und Flexibilität diese Dissertation teils nebenberuflich fertigstellen konnte.<br />

Eine wertvolle Quelle der Inspiration und Motivation waren mir auch die ‚Desperate<br />

Docs‘ – mein Dank geht an Dr. Eva Bilhuber, Dr. Anne-Kathrin Lohbeck, Pr<strong>of</strong>. Dr.<br />

Markus Menz, Dr. Philipp Stradtmann sowie Carola Wolf für die angeregten<br />

Diskussionen und das stets harte aber herzliche Challenging. Für die Ermöglichung<br />

meiner Fallstudien und die Unterstützung während meiner empirischen Phase danke<br />

ich Dr. Martin Everts (Axpo AG), Björn Schigt (Holcim Ltd) und Marc Chariatte<br />

(ehemals Flughafen Zürich AG) sowie allen Interviewpartnern, die sich Zeit<br />

genommen und sich so engagiert eingebracht haben.<br />

Meinen grössten Dank möchte ich meiner Familie aussprechen, die mich während<br />

allen Phasen bedingungslos unterstützt hat: meinen Eltern für die Ermöglichung der<br />

iii


iv<br />

Acknowledgements<br />

Voraussetzungen, diese Dissertation überhaupt schreiben zu können und ihr<br />

Verständnis während der Erstellungsphase, sowie meiner Schwester Dr. Marion Ulmer<br />

für ihren wertvollen und motivierenden Rat und ihr immer <strong>of</strong>fenes Ohr, vor allem aber<br />

für ihre tatkräftige Unterstützung in der Schlussphase des Projektes. Für seine endlose<br />

Geduld und sein Verständnis, seine Bereitschaft, persönliche Bedürfnisse<br />

hintenanzustellen und seinen steten ermutigenden Zuspruch möchte ich an dieser<br />

Stelle meine tiefe Dankbarkeit an meinen Ehemann Pascal Kern zum Ausdruck<br />

bringen – dank ihm habe ich auch in Momenten des Zweifelns das Ziel nie aus den<br />

Augen verloren. Neben all den damit verbundenen Opfern hat uns diese Zeit vor allem<br />

weiter zusammengeschweisst und uns Gewissheit gegeben, dass wir unser Leben<br />

gemeinsam verbringen wollen – Dir, Pascal, soll daher diese Dissertation gewidmet<br />

sein.<br />

St. Gallen, August 2011 Annette Kern-Ulmer


Overview <strong>of</strong> Contents v<br />

Overview <strong>of</strong> Contents<br />

Acknowledgements ........................................................................................................ iii<br />

Overview <strong>of</strong> Contents ..................................................................................................... v<br />

Table <strong>of</strong> Contents .......................................................................................................... vii<br />

<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Figures, Tables, Appendices ............................................................................. xii<br />

<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Abbreviations .................................................................................................. xvii<br />

1 Introduction .................................................................................................................. 1<br />

1.1 Research objectives <strong>and</strong> guiding questions ....................................................... 4<br />

1.2 <strong>The</strong>oretical relevance ........................................................................................ 8<br />

1.3 Practical relevance ........................................................................................... 10<br />

1.4 Outline <strong>of</strong> dissertation ..................................................................................... 11<br />

2 <strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review ......................................................... 14<br />

2.1 Relevant concepts <strong>of</strong> strategic management research ..................................... 14<br />

2.2 Relevant concepts <strong>of</strong> economic geography ..................................................... 23<br />

2.3 Relevant concepts <strong>of</strong> (new) institutionalism ................................................... 27<br />

2.4 Relevant concepts <strong>of</strong> economic sociology ...................................................... 30<br />

2.5 Relevant concepts <strong>of</strong> value creation ................................................................ 35<br />

2.6 Conclusion ....................................................................................................... 38<br />

3 Empirical Approach ................................................................................................... 41<br />

3.1 Research paradigm <strong>and</strong> research perspective .................................................. 41<br />

3.2 Research methodology .................................................................................... 42<br />

3.3 Case research ................................................................................................... 45<br />

3.4 Research design ............................................................................................... 47<br />

3.5 Research process ............................................................................................. 56<br />

3.6 Methods ........................................................................................................... 58<br />

3.7 Research quality .............................................................................................. 62<br />

3.8 Conclusion ....................................................................................................... 68<br />

4 <strong>The</strong>ory Building ......................................................................................................... 69<br />

4.1 Space, place <strong>and</strong> scale ..................................................................................... 69


vi<br />

Overview <strong>of</strong> Contents<br />

4.2 Institutions ....................................................................................................... 71<br />

4.3 Conceptual framework development .............................................................. 74<br />

4.4 Part one - embedded single unit perspective ................................................... 78<br />

4.5 <strong>Location</strong>-fixity ................................................................................................. 81<br />

4.6 Institutional exposure ...................................................................................... 87<br />

4.7 Moderators <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure ............................................................. 113<br />

4.8 Embedding capabilities <strong>of</strong> local management ............................................... 119<br />

4.9 Value creation ................................................................................................ 164<br />

4.10 Part two – multi-site perspective ............................................................... 192<br />

5 Case Studies ............................................................................................................. 220<br />

5.1 Case study - energy utilities .......................................................................... 221<br />

5.2 Case study - airport industry ......................................................................... 247<br />

5.3 Case study - cement <strong>and</strong> building materials .................................................. 282<br />

5.4 Cross case comparison .................................................................................. 312<br />

6 Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions ................................................................... 329<br />

6.1 Summary <strong>of</strong> propositions .............................................................................. 333<br />

6.2 Contributions to theory .................................................................................. 334<br />

6.3 Contributions to practice ............................................................................... 339<br />

6.4 Limitations <strong>of</strong> the dissertation ....................................................................... 343<br />

6.5 Methodological <strong>and</strong> empirical limitations ..................................................... 343<br />

6.6 <strong>The</strong>oretical limitations ................................................................................... 345<br />

6.7 Directions for future research ........................................................................ 346<br />

6.8 Final conclusions ........................................................................................... 349<br />

Appendices .................................................................................................................. 352<br />

Bibliography ............................................................................................................... 367<br />

Curriculum Vitae Annette Karoline Ulmer ................................................................ 392


Table <strong>of</strong> Contents<br />

Table <strong>of</strong> Contents<br />

Acknowledgements ........................................................................................................ iii<br />

Overview <strong>of</strong> Contents ..................................................................................................... v<br />

Table <strong>of</strong> Contents .......................................................................................................... vii<br />

<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Figures, Tables, Appendices ............................................................................. xii<br />

<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Abbreviations .................................................................................................. xvii<br />

1 Introduction .................................................................................................................. 1<br />

1.1 Research objectives <strong>and</strong> guiding questions ....................................................... 4<br />

1.2 <strong>The</strong>oretical relevance ........................................................................................ 8<br />

1.3 Practical relevance ........................................................................................... 10<br />

1.4 Outline <strong>of</strong> dissertation ..................................................................................... 11<br />

2 <strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review ......................................................... 14<br />

2.1 Relevant concepts <strong>of</strong> strategic management research ..................................... 14<br />

2.1.1 Resource-based view ..................................................................................................... 15<br />

2.1.2 Capability-based view ................................................................................................... 17<br />

2.1.3 Relational view .............................................................................................................. 18<br />

2.1.4 Transaction cost economics ........................................................................................... 19<br />

2.1.5 Stakeholder theory ......................................................................................................... 21<br />

2.2 Relevant concepts <strong>of</strong> economic geography ..................................................... 23<br />

2.2.1 <strong>Location</strong> theory .............................................................................................................. 24<br />

2.2.2 New economic geography - the cultural turn ................................................................ 26<br />

2.3 Relevant concepts <strong>of</strong> (new) institutionalism ................................................... 27<br />

2.3.1 New institutional economics ......................................................................................... 28<br />

2.3.2 Legitimacy theory .......................................................................................................... 29<br />

2.4 Relevant concepts <strong>of</strong> economic sociology ...................................................... 30<br />

2.4.1 New economic sociology .............................................................................................. 31<br />

2.5 Relevant concepts <strong>of</strong> value creation ................................................................ 35<br />

2.5.1 Value creation within the RBV ..................................................................................... 36<br />

2.5.2 Value creation through synergy realisation ................................................................... 37<br />

2.6 Conclusion ....................................................................................................... 38<br />

3 Empirical Approach ................................................................................................... 41<br />

3.1 Research paradigm <strong>and</strong> research perspective .................................................. 41<br />

3.2 Research methodology .................................................................................... 42<br />

vii


viii<br />

Table <strong>of</strong> Contents<br />

3.2.1 Inductive research .......................................................................................................... 43<br />

3.2.2 Grounded theory ............................................................................................................ 44<br />

3.3 Case research ................................................................................................... 45<br />

3.4 Research design ............................................................................................... 47<br />

3.4.1 Conceptual framework .................................................................................................. 48<br />

3.4.2 Research object .............................................................................................................. 49<br />

3.4.3 Unit <strong>of</strong> analysis .............................................................................................................. 51<br />

3.4.4 Case selection ................................................................................................................ 52<br />

3.5 Research process ............................................................................................. 56<br />

3.6 Methods ........................................................................................................... 58<br />

3.6.1 Expert discussions <strong>and</strong> semi-structured interviews ....................................................... 58<br />

3.6.2 Data transcription .......................................................................................................... 60<br />

3.6.3 Document analysis ........................................................................................................ 60<br />

3.6.4 Protocols <strong>and</strong> documentation ........................................................................................ 61<br />

3.6.5 Coding <strong>and</strong> analysis ....................................................................................................... 61<br />

3.7 Research quality .............................................................................................. 62<br />

3.7.1 Validity .......................................................................................................................... 63<br />

3.7.2 Reliability ...................................................................................................................... 67<br />

3.8 Conclusion ....................................................................................................... 68<br />

4 <strong>The</strong>ory Building ......................................................................................................... 69<br />

4.1 Space, place <strong>and</strong> scale ..................................................................................... 69<br />

4.2 Institutions ....................................................................................................... 71<br />

4.2.1 Pillars <strong>of</strong> institutions ...................................................................................................... 71<br />

4.2.2 Institutional environment <strong>and</strong> institutional arrangements ............................................. 73<br />

4.2.3 Institutions <strong>and</strong> economic performance ......................................................................... 73<br />

4.2.4 Institutional distance - the liability <strong>of</strong> foreignness ........................................................ 74<br />

4.3 Conceptual framework development .............................................................. 74<br />

4.3.1 Research questions guiding the framework development ............................................. 75<br />

4.4 Part one - embedded single unit perspective ................................................... 78<br />

4.4.1 Central links <strong>and</strong> notions <strong>of</strong> the research framework .................................................... 79<br />

4.5 <strong>Location</strong>-fixity ................................................................................................. 81<br />

4.5.1 Resource-based location-fixity ...................................................................................... 84<br />

4.5.2 Market-based location-fixity ......................................................................................... 86<br />

4.5.3 Ownership-based location-fixity ................................................................................... 87<br />

4.6 Institutional exposure ...................................................................................... 87<br />

4.6.1 <strong>The</strong>oretical grounding <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure: stakeholder theory ............................ 88<br />

4.6.2 Legitimate stakeholders within the research framework ............................................... 93<br />

4.6.3 <strong>The</strong>oretical grounding <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure: transaction cost theory ..................... 97


Table <strong>of</strong> Contents<br />

4.6.4 Institutional exposure by identified stakeholder groups ................................................ 99<br />

4.6.5 Reciprocal exposure, self-interest <strong>and</strong> the notion <strong>of</strong> fairness ...................................... 110<br />

4.6.6 Differences in institutional environment <strong>and</strong> political system .................................... 112<br />

4.7 Moderators <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure ............................................................. 113<br />

4.7.1 <strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> the local economic relevance on institutional exposure .............................. 113<br />

4.7.2 <strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> competition on institutional exposure ......................................................... 116<br />

4.8 Embedding capabilities <strong>of</strong> local management ............................................... 119<br />

4.8.1 <strong>The</strong> concept <strong>of</strong> embeddedness ..................................................................................... 122<br />

4.8.2 Organisational legitimacy ............................................................................................ 126<br />

4.8.3 Attributes <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities ........................................................................... 129<br />

4.8.4 Structural (economic) embedding capabilities ............................................................ 130<br />

4.8.5 Relational (social) embedding capabilities .................................................................. 148<br />

4.8.6 Summary <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities ........................................................................... 162<br />

4.9 Value creation ................................................................................................ 164<br />

4.9.1 Value creation within the research framework ............................................................ 169<br />

4.9.2 Value through strategic options ................................................................................... 171<br />

4.9.3 Value through risk decrease ........................................................................................ 176<br />

4.9.4 Short-term (direct impact) value creation .................................................................... 180<br />

4.9.5 Summary <strong>of</strong> value creation effects in single-unit operations ...................................... 187<br />

4.10 Part two – multi-site perspective ............................................................... 192<br />

4.10.1 <strong>The</strong> role <strong>of</strong> the corporate parent .................................................................................. 193<br />

4.10.2 Inter-site collaboration <strong>and</strong> linkage formation ............................................................ 194<br />

4.10.3 Limitations to multi-site firms within UCI .................................................................. 195<br />

4.10.4 Value creation in the multi-site firm ........................................................................... 200<br />

4.10.5 UCF value creation in multi-site operations ................................................................ 202<br />

4.10.6 Relational dimension <strong>of</strong> multi-site value creation ....................................................... 203<br />

4.10.7 Resource dimension <strong>of</strong> multi-site value creation ........................................................ 206<br />

4.10.8 Institutional dimension <strong>of</strong> multi-site value creation .................................................... 211<br />

4.10.9 Summary <strong>of</strong> value creation effects in multi-site operations ........................................ 216<br />

5 Case Studies ............................................................................................................. 220<br />

5.1 Case study - energy utilities .......................................................................... 221<br />

5.1.1 Industry characteristics ................................................................................................ 222<br />

5.1.2 Swiss energy market .................................................................................................... 222<br />

5.1.3 <strong>The</strong> case <strong>of</strong> Axpo ......................................................................................................... 224<br />

5.1.4 Axpo's location-fixity .................................................................................................. 226<br />

5.1.5 Axpo's environment - institutional exposure ............................................................... 228<br />

5.1.6 Axpo's embedding capabilities .................................................................................... 232<br />

5.1.7 Value creation .............................................................................................................. 239<br />

5.1.8 Summary ..................................................................................................................... 246<br />

ix


x<br />

Table <strong>of</strong> Contents<br />

5.2 Case study - airport industry ......................................................................... 247<br />

5.2.1 Industry characteristics ................................................................................................ 247<br />

5.2.2 Swiss airport industry .................................................................................................. 249<br />

5.2.3 <strong>The</strong> case <strong>of</strong> Flughafen Zürich AG (Zurich Airport) .................................................... 250<br />

5.2.4 Flughafen Zürich AG's location-fixity ........................................................................ 254<br />

5.2.5 Flughafen Zürich AG's environment - institutional exposure ..................................... 256<br />

5.2.6 Flughafen Zürich AG's embedding capabilities .......................................................... 262<br />

5.2.7 Value creation .............................................................................................................. 272<br />

5.2.8 Summary ..................................................................................................................... 281<br />

5.3 Case study - cement <strong>and</strong> building materials .................................................. 282<br />

5.3.1 Industry characteristics ................................................................................................ 283<br />

5.3.2 Swiss cement <strong>and</strong> building materials market .............................................................. 285<br />

5.3.3 <strong>The</strong> case <strong>of</strong> Holcim ...................................................................................................... 285<br />

5.3.4 Holcim's location-fixity ............................................................................................... 289<br />

5.3.5 Holcim's environment - institutional exposure ............................................................ 290<br />

5.3.6 Holcim's legitimisation capabilities ............................................................................. 294<br />

5.3.7 Value creation .............................................................................................................. 303<br />

5.3.8 Summary ..................................................................................................................... 311<br />

5.4 Cross case comparison .................................................................................. 312<br />

5.4.1 Comparison <strong>of</strong> location-fixity ..................................................................................... 312<br />

5.4.2 Commonalities <strong>and</strong> differences in institutional exposure ............................................ 314<br />

5.4.3 Comparison <strong>of</strong> legitimisation <strong>and</strong> embedding strategies ............................................. 316<br />

5.4.4 Comparison <strong>of</strong> value creation effects .......................................................................... 320<br />

5.4.5 Summary & conclusion ............................................................................................... 326<br />

6 Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions ................................................................... 329<br />

6.1 Summary <strong>of</strong> propositions .............................................................................. 333<br />

6.2 Contributions to theory .................................................................................. 334<br />

6.2.1 Conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> location-fixity ............................................................................ 335<br />

6.2.2 Conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure ................................................................ 336<br />

6.2.3 Identification <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities as value-creating factor ............................... 337<br />

6.2.4 Enabling assets - linking institutional <strong>and</strong> strategic approaches ................................. 337<br />

6.2.5 Utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based firms - a new perspective ........................................... 338<br />

6.3 Contributions to practice ............................................................................... 339<br />

6.3.1 Long-term view <strong>of</strong> relationship building with stakeholders ........................................ 340<br />

6.3.2 Underst<strong>and</strong>ing location-fixity's impacts <strong>and</strong> mitigation possibilities .......................... 341<br />

6.3.3 Alternative approach to business development ........................................................... 342<br />

6.3.4 Affirmation <strong>of</strong> value creation opportunities in UCF multi-site operations ................. 342<br />

6.3.5 Identification <strong>of</strong> new peer group for exchange ............................................................ 343


Table <strong>of</strong> Contents<br />

6.4 Limitations <strong>of</strong> the dissertation ....................................................................... 343<br />

6.5 Methodological <strong>and</strong> empirical limitations ..................................................... 343<br />

6.6 <strong>The</strong>oretical limitations ................................................................................... 345<br />

6.7 Directions for future research ........................................................................ 346<br />

6.7.1 Methodological <strong>and</strong> empirical directions .................................................................... 347<br />

6.7.2 <strong>The</strong>oretical directions .................................................................................................. 347<br />

6.8 Final conclusions ........................................................................................... 349<br />

Appendices .................................................................................................................. 352<br />

Bibliography ............................................................................................................... 367<br />

Curriculum Vitae Annette Karoline Ulmer ................................................................ 392<br />

xi


xii<br />

<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Figures, Tables, Appendices<br />

<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Figures<br />

<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Figures, Tables, Appendices<br />

Figure 1-1: Worldwide development <strong>of</strong> power deal activity .......................................... 1<br />

Figure 1-2: Simplified (single-site) research framework, part one ................................. 5<br />

Figure 1-3: Simplified (multi-site) research framework, part two ................................. 7<br />

Figure 1-4: Outline <strong>of</strong> dissertation ................................................................................ 13<br />

Figure 3-1: Basic types <strong>of</strong> case study designs .............................................................. 46<br />

Figure 3-2: Simplified research framework <strong>and</strong> reference to research questions ........ 49<br />

Figure 3-3: Inductive research process ......................................................................... 56<br />

Figure 3-4: <strong>The</strong>oretical sampling process to saturation ................................................ 60<br />

Figure 4-1: Conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> space, place <strong>and</strong> scale .............................................. 70<br />

Figure 4-2: Simplified conceptual framework <strong>and</strong> references to subchapters ............. 79<br />

Figure 4-3: Types <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> corresponding references to subchapters ..... 81<br />

Figure 4-4: Immobility-inducing resources .................................................................. 85<br />

Figure 4-5: Internal <strong>and</strong> external stakeholder classification ......................................... 90<br />

Figure 4-6: Institutional exposure <strong>and</strong> stakeholder groups within the research<br />

framework ..................................................................................................................... 97<br />

Figure 4-7: Moderators between location-fixity <strong>and</strong> institutional exposure .............. 113<br />

Figure 4-8: Influence <strong>of</strong> aggressive competition on institutional exposure ............... 119<br />

Figure 4-9: Embedding capabilities as action parameter towards value creation ...... 120<br />

Figure 4-10: Objectives <strong>of</strong> the firm's embedding capabilities .................................... 121<br />

Figure 4-11: Attributes <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities within the research framework ... 130<br />

Figure 4-12: Virtuous cycle between value share remaining in region <strong>and</strong> rent ........ 134<br />

Figure 4-13: Principal forms <strong>of</strong> governance ............................................................... 139<br />

Figure 4-14: Links between relational embedding capabilities <strong>and</strong> value creation ... 149<br />

Figure 4-15: Spectrum <strong>of</strong> stakeholder engagement .................................................... 150


<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Figures, Tables, Appendices xiii<br />

Figure 4-16: Value creation as the dependent (output) variable within the research<br />

framework ................................................................................................................... 164<br />

Figure 4-17: Conception <strong>of</strong> use value creation ........................................................... 166<br />

Figure 4-18: Part two <strong>of</strong> the research framework ....................................................... 193<br />

Figure 4-19: Alternative political management strategies .......................................... 214<br />

Figure 5-1: Market shares in Switzerl<strong>and</strong>'s electricity supply (2008/2009) ............... 223<br />

Figure 5-2: Swiss electricity generation mix .............................................................. 223<br />

Figure 5-3: Axpo's organisational structure ................................................................ 225<br />

Figure 5-4: Axpo's presence in Europe (2009) ........................................................... 226<br />

Figure 5-5: Chronology <strong>of</strong> airport privatisations & transactions ................................ 248<br />

Figure 5-6: Functional organisation <strong>of</strong> Flughafen Zürich AG .................................... 251<br />

Figure 5-7: International engagements <strong>of</strong> Flughafen Zürich AG (2010) ................... 252<br />

Figure 5-8: Primary business models in international airport activities ..................... 253<br />

Figure 5-9: Field <strong>of</strong> tension between Zurich airport <strong>and</strong> its environment .................. 256<br />

Figure 5-10: Cement production process <strong>and</strong> associated externalities ....................... 283<br />

Figure 5-11: Holcim's global presence (2009) ............................................................ 287<br />

Figure 5-12: Holcim's sales per region in percent (2009) ........................................... 288<br />

Figure 5-13: Holcim's pillars <strong>of</strong> value creation .......................................................... 303<br />

Figure 5-14: Holcim's development <strong>of</strong> alternative fuel use ........................................ 306<br />

Figure 5-15: Different embedding focus over asset lifetime - Axpo <strong>and</strong> Zurich<br />

Airport ......................................................................................................................... 318<br />

Figure 6-1: Overview on derived propositions <strong>and</strong> affiliation with research<br />

framework ................................................................................................................... 333<br />

Figure 6-2: Intensity <strong>of</strong> embedding activities over asset life-time / duration <strong>of</strong><br />

concession ................................................................................................................... 341


xiv<br />

<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Tables<br />

<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Figures, Tables, Appendices<br />

Table 2-1: Overview on relevant theoretical streams <strong>and</strong> concepts ............................. 14<br />

Table 2-2: <strong>The</strong>oretical perspectives in economic geography ....................................... 24<br />

Table 2-3: Summary <strong>of</strong> key elements from the relevant theoretical research lenses ... 40<br />

Table 3-1: Categorisation <strong>of</strong> research questions ........................................................... 48<br />

Table 3-2: Overview case study objects <strong>and</strong> selection criteria ..................................... 55<br />

Table 3-3: Internal validity through triangulation ........................................................ 66<br />

Table 4-1: Three pillars <strong>of</strong> institutions ......................................................................... 72<br />

Table 4-2: Types <strong>and</strong> characteristics <strong>of</strong> location-fixity ................................................ 83<br />

Table 4-3: UCF characteristics fostering institutional exposure .................................. 94<br />

Table 4-4: Legitimate stakeholder groups pertaining to UCFs .................................... 96<br />

Table 4-5: Government's roles, objectives <strong>and</strong> related institutional exposure ........... 106<br />

Table 4-6: Levers <strong>of</strong> structural embeddedness <strong>and</strong> organisational legitimacy ........... 132<br />

Table 4-7 Holcim's types <strong>of</strong> stakeholder engagement at the local level ..................... 151<br />

Table 4-8: Efficiency <strong>and</strong> strategy-based advantages <strong>of</strong> corporate reputation ........... 155<br />

Table 4-9: Efficiency <strong>and</strong> strategy-based advantages <strong>of</strong> trusting relationships ......... 158<br />

Table 4-10: Summary <strong>and</strong> operationalisation <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities .................. 163<br />

Table 4-11: Conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> value creation within the research framework ...... 169<br />

Table 4-12: Type <strong>of</strong> exchange <strong>and</strong> effects on firm transaction costs ......................... 181<br />

Table 4-13: Summary <strong>of</strong> value creation dimensions <strong>and</strong> effects in single-unit<br />

operations .................................................................................................................... 190<br />

Table 4-14: Links between UCFs' embedding capabilities <strong>and</strong> value creation .......... 191<br />

Table 4-15: Value creation effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity for the UCF ............................. 192<br />

Table 4-16: Examples <strong>of</strong> economic nationalism in national strategic sectors ............ 198<br />

Table 4-17: Typology <strong>of</strong> synergies for multi-site firms ............................................. 202<br />

Table 4-18: Holcim's government relations 91 ............................................................. 216<br />

Table 4-19: Overview on dimensions, effects <strong>of</strong> value creation in UCF multi-site<br />

operations .................................................................................................................... 219


<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Figures, Tables, Appendices xv<br />

Table 5-1: Sources <strong>of</strong> information for case studies .................................................... 221<br />

Table 5-2: <strong>Location</strong> dependence <strong>of</strong> Axpo by construct characteristics ...................... 227<br />

Table 5-3: Overview on Axpo's synergy implementation .......................................... 245<br />

Table 5-4: <strong>Location</strong> dependence <strong>of</strong> Flughafen Zürich AG by construct<br />

characteristics .............................................................................................................. 255<br />

Table 5-5: Overall value added <strong>of</strong> Zurich airport (2004) ........................................... 263<br />

Table 5-6: Overview on Zurich airport’s synergy implementation ............................ 279<br />

Table 5-7: Net sales volumes <strong>of</strong> top five cement producers (2009) ........................... 284<br />

Table 5-8: Operating pr<strong>of</strong>it margins <strong>of</strong> top five cement producers ............................ 286<br />

Table 5-9: <strong>Location</strong> dependence <strong>of</strong> Holcim by construct characteristics ................... 290<br />

Table 5-10: Holcim's community spending per category (2009) ............................... 295<br />

Table 5-11: Overview on Holcim's synergy implementation ..................................... 310<br />

Table 5-12: Cross-case comparison <strong>of</strong> location-fixity: Axpo, Zurich Airport <strong>and</strong><br />

Holcim ......................................................................................................................... 314<br />

Table 5-13: Cross-case comparison <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure: Axpo, Zurich Airport<br />

<strong>and</strong> Holcim .................................................................................................................. 316<br />

Table 5-14: Fields <strong>of</strong> multi-site value creation <strong>and</strong> their significance for<br />

case objects ................................................................................................................. 325<br />

Table 6-1: Overview on research questions <strong>and</strong> relevant sub-chapters reference ...... 330<br />

Table 6-2: Relevance <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities for managerial functions ............... 340


xvi<br />

<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Appendices<br />

Appendix 1: Overview on case study objects<br />

Appendix 2: <strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> interview partners<br />

Appendix 3: Interview guideline, example<br />

<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Figures, Tables, Appendices


<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Abbreviations xvii<br />

<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Abbreviations<br />

a/p airport<br />

ACI Airports Council International<br />

AFR alternative fuels <strong>and</strong> raw materials<br />

BAA British Airport Authority<br />

BIA Bengaluru International Airport<br />

BIAL Bangalore International Airport Ltd., i.e. the operator <strong>of</strong> BIA<br />

BKW Bernische Kraftwerke AG<br />

bn billion<br />

BRM business risk management, Holcim's corporate risk management<br />

department<br />

BU business unit<br />

CAP Community Advisory Panel<br />

CBV capability based view<br />

CC corporate centre<br />

CEO chief executive <strong>of</strong>ficer<br />

cf. confer (Lat. = compare, consult)<br />

CHF Swiss franc<br />

CFIUS Committee on Foreign Investment in the United States<br />

CSI Cement Sustainability Initiative<br />

CSR corporate social responsibility<br />

CSD corporate sustainable development<br />

DPW Dubai Ports World<br />

DVO Durchführungsverordnung; Implementation Regulation<br />

EMR Emission Monitoring <strong>and</strong> Reporting, Holcim's corporate st<strong>and</strong>ard for<br />

monitoring atmospheric emissions<br />

e.g. exempli gratia (Lat. = for instance)<br />

EnG Energiegesetz, Energy Law<br />

ENSI Eidgenössisches Nuklearsicherheitsinspektorat, Swiss Federal<br />

Nuclear Safety Inspectorate<br />

ESTI Eidgenössisches Starkstrominspektorat, Federal Inspectorate for<br />

Heavy Current Installations<br />

F&B food <strong>and</strong> beverage<br />

FDI foreign direct investment


xviii<br />

<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Abbreviations<br />

Fig. Figure<br />

FOLA Fernwärmeversorgung Olten-Aarau<br />

GB Great Britain<br />

GLOBE Global Legislators Organisation <strong>of</strong> a Balanced Environment<br />

GRI Global Reporting Initiative (www.globalreporting.org)<br />

GTZ Deutsche Gesellschaft Für Technische Zusammenarbeit, German<br />

Agency for Technical Cooperation<br />

HS AG Axpo Hydro Surselva AG<br />

HGRS Holcim Group Support<br />

ICAO International Civil Aviation Organization<br />

ICT Information <strong>and</strong> Communication Technology<br />

i.e. id est (Lat. = that is to)<br />

IO industrial organisation<br />

KEV kostendeckende Einspeiseverguetung, cost-covering feed-in<br />

compensation<br />

KLL Kraftwerke Linth-Limmern AG<br />

KWO Kraftwerke Oberhasli AG<br />

m million<br />

M&A mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions<br />

Mgmt. management<br />

MNC multi-national company or corporation<br />

MS multiple sites, multi site<br />

MSF multi site firm<br />

MW megawatt<br />

n/a not applicable<br />

NES new economic sociology<br />

NGO non-governmental organisation<br />

NIE new institutional economics<br />

N.N. nomen nescio (Lat. = anonymous person, name unknown)<br />

p. page<br />

P proposition<br />

PAX passengers<br />

PEP Plant Emission Pr<strong>of</strong>iles, Holcim's environmental assessment system<br />

POP persistent organic polluants


<strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> Abbreviations xix<br />

P&O Peninsular <strong>and</strong> Oriental Steam Navigation Company<br />

pp. pages<br />

RBV resource-based view<br />

R&D research & development<br />

REFUNA Regionales Fernwärmenetz Unteres Aaretal<br />

RQ research question<br />

SBFZ Schutzverb<strong>and</strong> der Bevölkerung um den Flughafen Zürich, major<br />

noise-centred interest group <strong>of</strong> Zurich airport<br />

SD sustainable development<br />

SOE state-owned enterprise<br />

SRT SR Technics<br />

StromVG Stromversorgungsgesetz, Power Supply Law<br />

TCE transaction-cost economics<br />

TRANSWAL Transport Wärme Aare Limmattal<br />

TPAX transfer passengers<br />

UCF utility or concession-based firm, i.e. firms within UCI<br />

UCI utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based industries <strong>of</strong> national strategic<br />

importance<br />

UDF User Development Fee<br />

US United States<br />

UK United Kingdom<br />

VIP Very Important Person<br />

VVIP Very Very Important Person<br />

VPI vertical political integration<br />

VRIN valuable, rare, imperfectly imitable <strong>and</strong> imperfectly substitutable;<br />

characteristics <strong>of</strong> strategic resources within the RBV<br />

vs versus<br />

WARHENO Fernwärmeversorgung Hochrhein<br />

WBCSD World Business Council for Sustainable Development<br />

WWF World Wildlife Fund<br />

www world wide web


xx<br />

Abstract<br />

Keywords: location-fixity, embeddedness, organisational legitimacy, sunk costs, value creation<br />

Abstract<br />

<strong>Location</strong> - in spite <strong>of</strong> increasing globalisation <strong>of</strong> economic activities – also in present<br />

times remains central to firms’ success. While most firms have the freedom to choose<br />

or change their location, some face limitations to do so. Yet, previous research barely<br />

considered the effects <strong>of</strong> location-dependence in the field <strong>of</strong> organisation studies. In<br />

addition, research has paid little attention to the spatially immobile infrastructure<br />

sector, which is bound to a location for the long-term through significant sunk costs.<br />

This dissertation addresses both gaps. It aims to contribute – among others - to<br />

strategic management research by integrating a spatial dimension, <strong>and</strong> to enhance a<br />

firm-centric perspective in economic geography. More specifically, we address<br />

impacts <strong>of</strong> location-fixity on firms’ value creation with a focus on infrastructure-heavy<br />

firms, subsumed as utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-bound firms.<br />

In this study we conceptualise location fixity <strong>and</strong> investigate the firm's strategies <strong>and</strong><br />

capabilities to mitigate any negative impacts, which could affect its value creation. In a<br />

first part, we approach the related research questions with view at single sites, before<br />

turning to aspects <strong>of</strong> value creation <strong>and</strong> synergy realisation within multi-site settings.<br />

To this end, we conducted an embedded multiple case study on three firms within<br />

infrastructure-heavy industries, thus collecting rich evidence for further theory<br />

development.<br />

<strong>The</strong> key findings <strong>of</strong> this dissertation are: (1) <strong>Location</strong>-bound firms are highly<br />

dependent on local stakeholders. <strong>The</strong> thus resultant institutional exposure to their local<br />

environment may negatively influence their strategic options, business risks, <strong>and</strong><br />

economic aspects <strong>of</strong> daily operation. (2) Firms are able to mitigate institutional<br />

exposure by developing capabilities for embedding in their local environment. Such<br />

embedding increases their organisational legitimacy, thereby improving the firm's<br />

prospects for long-term success <strong>and</strong> support from its environment. (3) Internationally<br />

present location bound firms face liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness, entailing obstacles not<br />

existent to local firms. <strong>The</strong> corporate parent therefore is able to support the local firm<br />

in distinct fields, where it enhances value creation, whereas other fields need to be<br />

managed decentrally to facilitate local embedding. Overall, also the locationdependent<br />

utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based firms are able to create value through multisite<br />

resource management, albeit predominantly on an intangible dimension by<br />

exchanging best practices <strong>and</strong> realising economies <strong>of</strong> experience.


Abstract (German)<br />

Zusammenfassung<br />

Schlüsselwörter: St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit, Einbettung, Unternehmens-Legitimität, irreversible<br />

Kosten, Value Creation<br />

Der Unternehmensst<strong>and</strong>ort ist auch in der heutigen Zeit, trotz zunehmender Globalisierung<br />

wirtschaftlicher Aktivitäten, ein kritischer Erfolgsfaktor. Während die meisten Unternehmen frei<br />

sind, ihren St<strong>and</strong>ort zu wählen oder zu verändern, gibt es Firmen, die dies nicht so ohne weiteres<br />

können. Trotz dieses Umst<strong>and</strong>es hat sich die bisherige Organisationsforschung dem <strong>The</strong>ma<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit kaum angenommen. Ebenso findet der st<strong>and</strong>ortgebundene<br />

Infrastruktursektor, welcher sich auf Grund hoher irreversibler Kosten für einen langen<br />

Zeithorizont zu einer Örtlichkeit bekennt, wenig wissenschaftliche Beachtung. Die vorliegende<br />

Dissertation thematisiert diese beiden Forschungslücken mit dem Ziel, zur Integration der<br />

räumlichen Perspektive in die strategische Managementforschung beizutragen, sowie eine<br />

unternehmensbezogene Betrachtung innerhalb des Bereichs der Wirtschaftsgeographie zu fördern.<br />

Im Besonderen beschäftigt sie sich mit den Auswirkungen von St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit auf die<br />

unternehmerischen Möglichkeiten zur Wertsteigerung, mit Fokus auf die Gruppe der Utilities und<br />

konzessionsgebundenen Unternehmen.<br />

Die Studie beinhaltet eine Konzeptionalisierung von St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit, sowie die<br />

Untersuchung von Strategien und Fähigkeiten, mit denen Unternehmen mögliche dadurch<br />

entstehende Nachteile für ihre Wertgenerierung auffangen können. Die sich daraus ergebenden<br />

Forschungsfragen werden zuerst mit Blick auf einzelne St<strong>and</strong>orte untersucht, und in einem<br />

zweiten Teil aus der Perspektive eines Unternehmens mit meheren St<strong>and</strong>orten. Auf der Basis<br />

einer vergleichenden Fallstudienanalyse von drei Objekten, welche im Bereich der Utilities und<br />

konzessionsgebundenen Unternehmen angesiedelt sind, haben wir Erkenntnisse gesammelt,<br />

welche einer weitergehenden <strong>The</strong>oriebildung dienen.<br />

Die Haupterkenntnisse dieser Dissertation können wie folgt beschrieben werden: (1)<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundene Unternehmen erfahren eine hohe Abhängigkeit von ihren örtlichen<br />

Stakeholdern, mit möglichen negativen Auswirkungen auf ihre strategischen Optionen,<br />

Unternehmensrisiken und ihre Operation. (2) Mit Hilfe von spezifischen Fähigkeiten zur<br />

Einbettung ins lokale Umfeld können Unternehmen die Nachteile einer solchen institutionellen<br />

Exposure auffangen. Dadurch erhöhen sie ihre unternehmerische Legimitation und sichern die<br />

Unterstützung durch das lokale Umfeld, um somit die langfristigen Erfolgschancen zu stärken. (3)<br />

Internationale Unternehmen erfahren im jeweiligen lokalen Umfeld ihrer St<strong>and</strong>orte Nachteile,<br />

welche lokal angestammte Firmen nicht haben. Daraus ergeben sich für das Mutterunternehmen<br />

bestimmte Bereiche, in denen es das lokale Management unterstützen kann, aber auch spezifische<br />

Aufgaben die dezentral verankert sein müssen, um die lokale Einbettung des Unternehmens zu<br />

stärken. Insgesamt sind auch st<strong>and</strong>ortgebundene Unternehmen in der Lage, durch das<br />

Management mehrerer St<strong>and</strong>orte Wert zu generieren, wenn auch mehrheitlich auf Ebene eines<br />

immateriellen Ressourcenaustausches.<br />

xxi


Introduction 1<br />

1 Introduction<br />

In today's globalised world the mobility <strong>of</strong> production factors <strong>and</strong> resources is an<br />

elementary precondition to the functioning <strong>of</strong> our economy. As the geographical<br />

disconnection <strong>of</strong> production processes re-defines sectoral structures <strong>and</strong> shifts the<br />

world's economic balance, firms are facing new challenges but also significant new<br />

possibilities. Footloose industries, with predominantly mobile production factors,<br />

may seize opportunities for new forms <strong>of</strong> sourcing, economies <strong>of</strong> scale <strong>and</strong> scope,<br />

<strong>and</strong> location-related cost advantages. In contrast, other industries are confined in<br />

their means to exploit these options. Infrastructure-heavy sectors, for instance,<br />

whose exponents are committed to a location for long periods <strong>of</strong> time, need to<br />

perform their whole range <strong>of</strong> core activities locally by the very nature <strong>of</strong> their<br />

activities. <strong>The</strong>se sectors will be the object <strong>of</strong> interest in our research.<br />

Restrictions to mobility affect a number <strong>of</strong> vital industries, in particular providers<br />

<strong>of</strong> large-scale infrastructures, i.e. (1) transportation assets, such as airports,<br />

railways, <strong>and</strong> seaports; (2) utility networks, inluding gas, water, <strong>and</strong> electricity;<br />

<strong>and</strong> (3) resource extraction facilities, pertaining to quarries <strong>and</strong> mines, <strong>of</strong>fshore<br />

platforms, or pipelines. Distinct as they are from each other, they all have in<br />

common certain characteristics which tie them to their place <strong>of</strong> production. And<br />

yet, many <strong>of</strong> these industries have gone through a phase internationalisation <strong>and</strong><br />

consolidation throughout the last quarter <strong>of</strong> a century, exp<strong>and</strong>ing horizontally <strong>and</strong><br />

vertically in their value chain (see also Schedler & Bieger, 2002). For instance, the<br />

past decade saw a massive consolidation process in the power sector, as illustrated<br />

in Figure 1-1, with the emergence <strong>of</strong> global power suppliers, such as E.ON, EdF,<br />

GdF Suez, RWE or Vattenfall.<br />

Figure 1-1: Worldwide development <strong>of</strong> power deal activity 1<br />

1 PWC, 2009: 8.


2<br />

Introduction<br />

Similar developments have taken place in the water utility sector (e.g. Veolia, once<br />

again GdF Suez <strong>and</strong> RWE, ITT, or Acqua America), the cement industry (e.g.<br />

Lafarge, Holcim, HeidelbergCement, Cemex, Italcementi), the port industry (e.g.<br />

Hutchison Port, PSA International, APM Terminals, Cosco <strong>and</strong> DP World) <strong>and</strong> to<br />

some extent also in the airport industry (e.g. Fraport, TAV, MAp Airports Ltd.,<br />

Hochtief AirPorts, GMR). To illustrate the worldwide dimension <strong>of</strong> these<br />

structural changes, the OECD (2007) estimates that large-scale transactions<br />

involving public infrastructure assets amounted to almost USD 1 trillion between<br />

1980 <strong>and</strong> 2006 in OECD countries.<br />

In Europe, these developments were facilitated by the European Community which<br />

aimed at liberalising markets for public utilities <strong>and</strong> brought the era <strong>of</strong> central<br />

planning to an end. Through the regulatory reforms, domestic markets became<br />

increasingly integrated with the global economy, reduced the role <strong>of</strong> government,<br />

<strong>and</strong> promoted market mechanisms to regulate the economy (Ray, 2003). <strong>The</strong><br />

adoption <strong>of</strong> market-based policies (deregulation) <strong>and</strong> the introduction <strong>of</strong> new<br />

regulatory frameworks (reregulation) (Ugaz & Price, 2003), presented firms with a<br />

wide range <strong>of</strong> strategic options, reshaping sectoral networks <strong>and</strong> construing fresh<br />

relationships between established actors (Dudley, 1999). Additionally,<br />

technological change created opportunities for sectors, where previously<br />

monopolistic structures seemed to be the most efficient <strong>and</strong> politically desirable<br />

solution. As a consequence to such removal <strong>of</strong> entry-barriers, increase in<br />

competition <strong>and</strong> the privatisation <strong>of</strong> formerly state-dominated industries,<br />

companies were free to follow strategies <strong>of</strong> expansion <strong>and</strong> internationalisation.<br />

Thus, they could exploit the resulting new possibilities while using their core<br />

competence in managing heavy-infrastructure assets (Parker, 2003). <strong>The</strong><br />

motivations to exp<strong>and</strong>, inter alia, sprang from expectations to realise economies <strong>of</strong><br />

scale <strong>and</strong> scope, to gain access to innovations in products <strong>and</strong> processes, <strong>and</strong> to<br />

benefit from the exchange <strong>of</strong> best practices.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se changes <strong>and</strong> their implications for the individual firm, for industry<br />

structures, <strong>and</strong> for whole economies also raised significant new research questions,<br />

which academics took to investigate from different perspectives. Within the scope<br />

<strong>of</strong> this dissertation we remain focused on the firm-level perspective, for which<br />

particularly strategic management research contributed to the discussion <strong>of</strong> related<br />

key issues. Much attention was given, for example, to questions <strong>of</strong> mobility<br />

barriers (e.g. R. E. Caves & Ghemawat, 1992; Lustgarten & Thomadakis, 1987;


Introduction 3<br />

Mahoney, 2001; Porter, 1979) <strong>and</strong> their role with regard to market power,<br />

competitive advantage <strong>and</strong> rent generation. Similarly, industry structures <strong>and</strong> the<br />

notion <strong>of</strong> strategic groups (e.g. Barney & Hoskisson, 1990; Dranove, Peteraf, &<br />

Shanley, 1998), as well as the formation <strong>of</strong> clusters <strong>and</strong> networks have been<br />

intensely discussed (e.g. Gulati, Nohria, & Zaheer, 2000; Lavie, 2007; Porter,<br />

1998), as have been issues <strong>of</strong> firms' internationalisation (e.g. Bartlett & Ghoshal,<br />

1989; Müller-Stewens & Lechner, 2002; Ruigrok & Wagner, 2003). From a<br />

different angle, the role <strong>of</strong> stakeholders <strong>and</strong> stakeholder management for the firm<br />

have been thoroughly researched (e.g. Clarkson, 1995; Phillips, 2003; Post,<br />

Preston, & Sachs, 2002b), leading to a theoretical appreciation <strong>of</strong> stakeholders'<br />

importance in view <strong>of</strong> the firm's long-term pr<strong>of</strong>itability. As strategic management<br />

research draws on central concepts from organisational economics - which<br />

acknowledges the importance <strong>of</strong> the firm's external environment beyond inter-firm<br />

interactions, but treats it as a black box - stakeholder theory contributed to<br />

extending the view <strong>of</strong> the firm to its context, integrating notions from<br />

institutionalism <strong>and</strong> economic sociology with strategic considerations.<br />

In spite <strong>of</strong> these significant theoretical <strong>and</strong> conceptual contributions, which also<br />

help to underst<strong>and</strong> the peculiarities <strong>of</strong> infrastructure-heavy industries - our object<br />

<strong>of</strong> interest - researchers have rarely focused on these sectors under consideration <strong>of</strong><br />

their common defining characteristics, which we identified as follows:<br />

- location-fixity <strong>and</strong> immobility <strong>of</strong> production factors<br />

- high capital <strong>and</strong> infrastructure intensity<br />

- long planning horizon<br />

- subadditive cost function<br />

- market power through quasi-monopolistic industry structures<br />

- quasi-public good character<br />

- high importance <strong>of</strong> output for the local economy, as key components <strong>of</strong><br />

large socio-technical systems (Gil & Beckman, 2009)<br />

- negative externalities<br />

- high public visibility<br />

- high regulatory density<br />

As a consequence <strong>of</strong> these characteristics, the majority <strong>of</strong> corresponding industries<br />

relies on public concessions to operate, which obliges them to perform their<br />

activities within a - more or less narrowly - defined scope <strong>and</strong> which grants them


4<br />

Introduction<br />

the right to exploit a certain resource, or to develop <strong>and</strong> to run an infrastructure at a<br />

dedicated location.<br />

<strong>The</strong> purpose <strong>of</strong> this study is, therefore, to contribute to the further integration <strong>of</strong> a<br />

contextual <strong>and</strong> strategic underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the firm in respect <strong>of</strong> industries, which<br />

fall under the specified criteria <strong>and</strong> which we chose as our research object. For<br />

matters <strong>of</strong> clarity, we aggregate these firms to the collective <strong>of</strong> Utilities <strong>and</strong><br />

Concession-based Firms (UCF), subsuming their industries under Utilities <strong>and</strong><br />

Concession-based Industries (UCI), accordingly. We therefore have chosen a<br />

multi-lens approach, which integrates other research perspectives besides the<br />

strategic management lens. In particular, we investigate the impact <strong>of</strong> the above<br />

mentioned industry characteristics on firms' capacity to create sustainable rents,<br />

<strong>and</strong> we examine the nature <strong>of</strong> location-fixity, its effects on firms' resource<br />

management, <strong>and</strong> in what ways these factors impact firms' value creation. To this<br />

end, we develop a two-parted framework, which first focuses on the effects <strong>of</strong><br />

location-fixity in a single-site context before analysing value creation impacts in a<br />

multi-site setting.<br />

1.1 Research objectives <strong>and</strong> guiding questions<br />

Throughout our dissertation, we underst<strong>and</strong> the firm's value creation to<br />

significantly depend on its resource disposition <strong>and</strong> on the organisation <strong>of</strong> its intrafirm<br />

activities, in the sense <strong>of</strong> the resource-based view <strong>of</strong> the firm. In addition, we<br />

attribute importance to the firm's environment, <strong>and</strong> how it interacts with, <strong>and</strong><br />

adapts to it. This underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> external context reaches beyond strategic<br />

management's focus on inter-firm interactions: it includes the firm's embedding in<br />

its local <strong>and</strong> institutional environment, <strong>and</strong> the role <strong>of</strong> firm-environment<br />

interactions for the creation <strong>of</strong> sustainable competitive advantage <strong>and</strong> rents. While<br />

these contextual factors are important for most firms, they are <strong>of</strong> particular<br />

relevance for our research object on grounds <strong>of</strong> the above identified industry<br />

characteristics. <strong>The</strong>refore, throughout our dissertation we will develop the<br />

argument that the UCF's sustainable livelihood depends on the relations with its<br />

local stakeholders, due to its immobility <strong>and</strong> financial long-term commitments to a<br />

location. In addition to strategic management research, we will draw on notions<br />

from various institutionalist perspectives, economic sociology, <strong>and</strong> from economic<br />

geography.


Introduction 5<br />

<strong>The</strong> research gap, which we have identified <strong>and</strong> will try to close, pertains to the<br />

characteristics <strong>of</strong> the UCF <strong>and</strong> the way in which they impact the UCF's ability to<br />

create value. In particular, we will analyse the construct <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> the<br />

related dependence <strong>of</strong> the firm on its local environment. We argue that these<br />

factors require a thorough embedding <strong>of</strong> the firm in its environment, in order to<br />

ensure long-term survival. <strong>The</strong> purpose <strong>of</strong> our work therefore is:<br />

- to obtain a better underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the construct <strong>of</strong> location-fixity,<br />

- to contribute to underst<strong>and</strong>ing the effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity - positive <strong>and</strong><br />

negative - on firms in general <strong>and</strong> UCFs in particular, <strong>and</strong> to generate<br />

insights on its effects in multi-site operations,<br />

- to derive from these insights recommendations strategies for value creation,<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

- to identify further areas for research.<br />

In the following, we will outline the research questions (RQ) addressed in this<br />

dissertation, as well as the two-parted framework which we developed throughout<br />

the research process. <strong>The</strong> first <strong>and</strong> dominant part <strong>of</strong> the research framework<br />

employs a single-site perspective <strong>of</strong> the firm. In the second part we will outline<br />

UCFs' possibilities for value creation in multi-site settings, based on the insights in<br />

part one.<br />

In part one <strong>of</strong> our research framework, we develop an underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the impacts<br />

<strong>of</strong> location-fixity on UCFs' possibilities for value creation, as illustrated in Figure<br />

1-2. We will outline the importance <strong>of</strong> the firm's capabilities to embed itself in its<br />

local environment, in order to mitigate the effects from any exposure resulting<br />

from its dependence on the location. <strong>The</strong>reby we are guided by the first four<br />

research questions, as laid out subsequently.<br />

RQ 1, RQ 2<br />

embedding<br />

capabilities<br />

local exposure from<br />

location fixity<br />

RQ 4 moderate<br />

RQ 3<br />

value creation<br />

influences<br />

Figure 1-2: Simplified (single-site) research framework, part one<br />

Developing the construct <strong>of</strong> location-fixity. In spite <strong>of</strong> the relevance <strong>of</strong> location<br />

for the sustained livelihood <strong>of</strong> most firms (Cox, 1998b; Dicken & Malmberg,<br />

2001; Ross, 1896), <strong>and</strong> the spatial immobility that firms may experience (Clark &


6<br />

Introduction<br />

Wrigley, 1995; Cox & Mair, 1988; Oinas, 1998), the factors that cause such<br />

immobility <strong>and</strong> the construct <strong>of</strong> location-fixity in general have not been<br />

satisfactorily conceptualised in existing research. Cox (1989) may be a rare<br />

exemption, taking a step in that direction by circumscribing firms' local<br />

dependence to be rooted in a combination <strong>of</strong> long-lived fixed investments, the<br />

specificity <strong>of</strong> firms' exchanges, but also in the immobility <strong>of</strong> social relations. Since<br />

spatial immobility is a decisive characteristic <strong>of</strong> UCFs, which therefore constitutes<br />

a core construct <strong>of</strong> this dissertation, we begin our research by trying to underst<strong>and</strong><br />

firms' location-fixity <strong>and</strong> to conceptualise its dimensions. Consequently, our first<br />

research question is:<br />

Research Question 1: What are the defining elements <strong>of</strong> location-fixity?<br />

Consequences <strong>of</strong> location-fixity. On the basis <strong>of</strong>, <strong>and</strong> related to these insights the<br />

subsequent questions are concerned with the effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity for the firm.<br />

As the local actors are aware, that the firm is tied to its current site, the firm<br />

becomes somewhat exposed to them - a fact which we refer to as institutional<br />

exposure. In this context, we draw on notions from transaction-cost economics, in<br />

order to underst<strong>and</strong> the implications for the firm, <strong>and</strong> to identify the related<br />

hazards (OE Williamson, 1983, 1996). More precisely, we aim to underst<strong>and</strong> such<br />

exposure <strong>and</strong> its sources, as well as the limitations <strong>and</strong> opportunities which arise<br />

from it. <strong>The</strong>reto related, we are interested in the effects <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure on<br />

the firm's ability to create value. Thus, we obtain a deeper underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the<br />

UCF's interdependencies with its local environment <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> the nature <strong>of</strong> its<br />

institutional exposure with regard to the individual stakeholder groups. Our second<br />

<strong>and</strong> third research questions therefore are as follows:<br />

Research Question 2: How do location-fixity <strong>and</strong> the related institutional<br />

exposure affect our research object?<br />

Research Question 3: How does the resulting local exposure - as the<br />

amalgamation <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> institutional exposure - affect the value<br />

creation <strong>of</strong> our research object?<br />

Mitigation <strong>of</strong> the effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity. <strong>The</strong> insights from the preceding<br />

research questions are essential for identifying available strategies, with which the


Introduction 7<br />

firm may mitigate adverse effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity, or leverage related<br />

opportunities. In this regard, we would like to introduce the institutionalist concept<br />

<strong>of</strong> embeddedness, which underlines a contextual view <strong>of</strong> the firm. Economic<br />

action thus is understood as being “embedded in concrete, ongoing systems <strong>of</strong><br />

social relations” (Granovetter, 1985: 487), with the firm's institutional environment<br />

referring to “rules, norms, <strong>and</strong> beliefs surrounding economic activity that define or<br />

enforce socially acceptable economic behaviour” (Christine Oliver, 1997: 698).<br />

Importantly, the firm's long-term survival is seen to depend on “its ability to<br />

establish <strong>and</strong> maintain relationships within its entire network <strong>of</strong> stakeholders”<br />

(Post, Preston, & Sachs, 2002a: 7). In line with these notions, we therefore argue<br />

that the firm's capabilities to embed itself in the local environment play a<br />

significant role in the mitigation <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure. Consequently, our<br />

fourth research question is directed towards identifying these embedding<br />

capabilities <strong>and</strong> to underst<strong>and</strong>ing how they change the firm's local exposure in<br />

value-enhancing ways:<br />

Research Question 4: How can firms mitigate the effects <strong>of</strong> local exposure?<br />

With the analysis <strong>of</strong> the first four research questions we hope to sufficiently<br />

underst<strong>and</strong> the effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity on the value creation <strong>of</strong> single-site firms,<br />

<strong>and</strong> how the latter may mitigate such effects. <strong>The</strong> subsequent questions relate to<br />

the multi-site perspective <strong>of</strong> part two <strong>of</strong> our research framework, which builds on<br />

the insights from the first part.<br />

UCF - site<br />

- location-fixity<br />

- institutional exposure<br />

UCF - corporate parent<br />

value creation<br />

RQ 6<br />

interaction<br />

RQ 5<br />

UCF - site<br />

-location-fixity<br />

- institutional exposure<br />

local environment local environment<br />

Figure 1-3: Simplified (multi-site) research framework, part two


8<br />

Introduction<br />

Implications for cross-site value creation. After having developed an<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> its effects on the individual site, we focus on<br />

UCFs strategies for value creation in a multi-site environment. We will analyse<br />

how multi-site UCFs interact in value-enhancing ways among their units <strong>and</strong> sites,<br />

<strong>and</strong> in which ways the corporate parent contributes to value creation. In their<br />

multi-site interaction, UCFs not only need to overcome the confinement <strong>of</strong><br />

location-fixity, but also need to work around the differences in the local<br />

environments <strong>of</strong> their sites. Due to the high visibility <strong>of</strong> UCFs, these specific local<br />

environments require (politically) sensitive h<strong>and</strong>ling, whereby the experience <strong>of</strong><br />

the corporate parent may be beneficial, while its foreignness may prove a liability<br />

(S. Zaheer, 1995). Consequently, it is <strong>of</strong> interest to underst<strong>and</strong> the dimensions <strong>of</strong><br />

value creation for multi-site UCFs <strong>and</strong> to identify the available options for synergy<br />

exploitation, which results in the research questions five <strong>and</strong> six:<br />

Research Question 5: How does location-fixity impact our research object's<br />

multi-site resource management?<br />

Research Question 6: How can the multi-site UCF create value under the<br />

condition <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> local exposure?<br />

1.2 <strong>The</strong>oretical relevance<br />

Generally, by means <strong>of</strong> our research we aim at a better underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the<br />

characteristics <strong>and</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> factor immobility from a firm perspective. To this<br />

effect we employ multiple lenses, using the partially overlapping perspectives <strong>of</strong><br />

strategic management, new institutionalism, economic sociology, <strong>and</strong> economic<br />

geography. Despite the importance <strong>of</strong> location factors (e.g. Cantwell, 2009;<br />

Dunning, 2009; Tesch, 1980; HW Yeung, 2000) for the firm's sustained livelihood,<br />

the construct <strong>of</strong> location-fixity has not yet been adequately conceptualised in<br />

existing research. By developing an underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> its effects<br />

for the individual site-level, <strong>and</strong> in respect <strong>of</strong> cross-site value creation, on one h<strong>and</strong><br />

we aim to contribute to economic geography, which traditionally argues from a<br />

higher scale perspective 2 (Oinas, 1997). On the other h<strong>and</strong>, we aim to underline the<br />

relevance <strong>of</strong> the spatial dimension for economic actors within strategic<br />

2 Such as regions, clusters, or economies.


Introduction 9<br />

management research, <strong>and</strong> to extend the notion <strong>of</strong> asset specificity by a spatial<br />

dimension.<br />

In addition, we intend to contribute to a better underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the firm's<br />

institutional exposure to its stakeholder groups. In particular, we develop a<br />

conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> the multiple roles <strong>of</strong> the firm's public stakeholders 3 <strong>and</strong> the<br />

possible resulting conflicts <strong>of</strong> interest that might adversely affect the firm.<br />

Moreover, in our research framework we attribute significant importance to the<br />

firm's local institutional context, drawing on the notion <strong>of</strong> embeddedness.<br />

Originating from economic sociology (Granovetter, 1985; K. Polanyi, 1944), the<br />

notion <strong>of</strong> embeddedness has only hesitantly found consideration within strategic<br />

management research, predominantly with regard to firms' embedding within<br />

networks <strong>and</strong> dyadic relations (e.g. Dyer & Singh, 1998; Lavie, 2007; Christine<br />

Oliver, 1997; Uzzi, 1996). We thus seek to integrate the notion <strong>of</strong> local<br />

embeddedness, which is a central concept <strong>of</strong> new institutionalism, with strategic<br />

management research's focus on rent-seeking <strong>and</strong> value creation. Furthermore, we<br />

aim to identify <strong>and</strong> contribute to an underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> those capabilities, which help<br />

the firm to strengthen its local embeddedness in value creating ways.<br />

By considering the firm's institutional context as relevant for the firm's capacity to<br />

generate rents, we additionally aim to exp<strong>and</strong> the boundary <strong>of</strong> strategy process<br />

research 4 towards acknowledging social explanations for effects <strong>of</strong> the<br />

environment on the firm's success. Thus, we take into account firms' pathdependent<br />

embedding activities towards building goodwill stocks, which allow it<br />

to influence its relations with the public stakeholders in value creating ways.<br />

Consequently, we add to a more holistic underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the complex<br />

interdependencies between the firm <strong>and</strong> its external environment.<br />

3<br />

We have defined public stakeholders to refer to the government, the regulator, <strong>and</strong> the state as a<br />

shareholder, see also chapter four.<br />

4<br />

We underst<strong>and</strong> strategy process research according to Van de Ven (1992: 169), who<br />

distinguishes three different meanings <strong>of</strong> process used in the literature: (1) a logic in order to<br />

explain a causal relationship in a variance theory; (2) referring to a category <strong>of</strong> concepts with<br />

regard to actions <strong>of</strong> individuals or organisations; <strong>and</strong> (3) a sequence <strong>of</strong> events that describes<br />

changes <strong>of</strong> things over time. We consider our research to fall into the second category <strong>of</strong> process<br />

research.


10<br />

1.3 Practical relevance<br />

Introduction<br />

While it would be st<strong>and</strong>ing to reason, that the relevance <strong>of</strong> location is declining in<br />

an increasingly globalised world, it seems that the opposite is true. Firms'<br />

competitive advantages are <strong>of</strong>ten local, rooted in their embeddedness with their<br />

environment <strong>and</strong> stakeholders (Dyer & Singh, 1998; Christine Oliver, 1997), as<br />

Porter (1998: 90) observes: “[g]eographic, cultural, <strong>and</strong> institutional proximity<br />

leads to special access, closer relationships, better information, powerful<br />

incentives, <strong>and</strong> other advantages in productivity <strong>and</strong> innovation that are difficult to<br />

tap from a distance”. We have outlined before, that the past twenty years <strong>of</strong><br />

deregulation have had significant effects on industry structures across the world,<br />

resulting in a consolidation process throughout infrastructure-heavy industries. On<br />

these grounds, we presume that executives <strong>of</strong> UCFs, as well as regional<br />

administrations take interest in the challenges, which are related to tensions<br />

between the 'local' <strong>and</strong> increasingly large firm operations. Throughout our<br />

empirical research, the relevance <strong>of</strong> the 'local' was affirmed by representatives <strong>of</strong><br />

our case objects, illustrated by the following statement by an executive from Axpo<br />

(cf. interview N°1: 12):<br />

<strong>Local</strong> embeddedness is the decisive factor for our sustained livelihood - all our<br />

endeavours depend on the approval <strong>of</strong> our local stakeholders. Without their<br />

consent we would have not a single production site, no revenue source, <strong>and</strong> as a<br />

consequence no firm!<br />

Furthermore, according to an empirical study on corporate mergers in the energy<br />

sector, synergy exploitation is a significant motivation behind these mergers<br />

(Thomas, 2006). <strong>The</strong> same applies to other utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-bound<br />

industries, albeit to varying degrees. Yet, practical experiences with the postmerger<br />

integration <strong>of</strong> firms have yielded mixed results (Bishara & Schmitt, 2006;<br />

Forsyth, Niemeier, & Wolf, 2011; N.N, 2007; N.N., 2004), with synergy<br />

expectations <strong>of</strong>ten being inflated compared to the final outcome. <strong>The</strong>refore it can<br />

be assumed, that an underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the ways in which location-fixity impacts<br />

value creation in firms' multi-site operations is <strong>of</strong> practical relevance.<br />

Consequently, we consider our research subject to be relevant for managers <strong>of</strong><br />

utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based industries <strong>and</strong> for public administrations, <strong>of</strong>fering an<br />

alternative view on the characteristics <strong>and</strong> challenges <strong>of</strong> infrastructure-heavy firms.<br />

We identify three practical main contributions <strong>of</strong> our work: (1) Our findings stress<br />

the path-dependence <strong>of</strong> firms' activities in their local environment, thus inducing


Introduction 11<br />

managers to take a longer-term view on their stakeholder-relations. By establishing<br />

a contextual link between local embedding <strong>and</strong> the firm's value-creation<br />

opportunities, corporate managers therefore might attribute more value to the<br />

firm's relations with its environment. (2) In our empirical research we describe,<br />

how location-fixity affects the firm <strong>and</strong> how, as a consequence, value creation may<br />

be adversely impacted. Our identification <strong>of</strong> mitigation strategies may contribute<br />

to better focused managerial efforts towards local embedding, thus shielding firms<br />

from the unwanted effects <strong>of</strong> local dependence. In addition, managers may derive<br />

impulses for their approach to local business development, thus leveraging the<br />

positive aspects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity to the firm's advantage. (3) Our empirical<br />

research affirms the possibilities for value creation <strong>of</strong> location-fixed firms in the<br />

operation <strong>of</strong> multiple sites. <strong>The</strong>se insights may thus contribute to a better<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the local firm's needs <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> those fields, where the corporate<br />

parent's support creates value.<br />

1.4 Outline <strong>of</strong> dissertation<br />

This dissertation is structured into six chapters, starting with the present chapter<br />

one to provide an introduction to the research subject <strong>and</strong> objectives. <strong>The</strong> four<br />

ensuing chapters comprise the theoretical embedding <strong>and</strong> clarification <strong>of</strong> the<br />

research lenses (chapter two), the description <strong>of</strong> the research approach (chapter<br />

three), the building <strong>and</strong> theoretical grounding <strong>of</strong> our research framework (chapter<br />

four), <strong>and</strong> the empirical illustration by means <strong>of</strong> three case studies (chapter five),<br />

before concluding with our findings <strong>and</strong> recommendations in chapter six.<br />

In chapter two we clarify the research lenses, which we employ in the chosen<br />

multi-lens approach. In order to familiarise the reader with the relevant concepts,<br />

we briefly describe the central notions <strong>of</strong> these lenses in view <strong>of</strong> our research<br />

questions, thus touching upon strategic management research, economic<br />

geography, (new) institutionalism, <strong>and</strong> economic sociology. We also highlight in<br />

each sub-chapter, how the concepts <strong>and</strong> constructs relate to our research<br />

framework.<br />

<strong>The</strong> third chapter informs on the chosen research approach <strong>and</strong> how we proceeded<br />

to investigate our research questions. We describe the employed research<br />

methodology, grounded theory, <strong>and</strong> the reasons for selecting an embedded multiple<br />

case design with three case objects from different industries. Furthermore, we<br />

clarify the cornerstones <strong>of</strong> our two-parted research framework, which is divided in


12<br />

Introduction<br />

a single-site <strong>and</strong> in a multi-site perspective. Under the single-site perspective, the<br />

firm <strong>and</strong> the capabilities <strong>of</strong> its managers are considered as units <strong>of</strong> analysis. In<br />

contrast, the multi-site perspective focuses on the corporate parent's interaction<br />

with its subsidiaries, respectively on the interaction among the subsidiaries as unit<br />

<strong>of</strong> analysis. <strong>The</strong> chapter also addresses aspects <strong>of</strong> research quality <strong>and</strong> the<br />

measures which we took to safeguard the validity <strong>and</strong> reliability <strong>of</strong> our results.<br />

In the forth chapter, which represents the core <strong>of</strong> this dissertation, we develop our<br />

research framework <strong>and</strong> central constructs, <strong>and</strong> consequently derive propositions<br />

based on our empirical insights. We theoretically ground essential notions, such as<br />

location-fixity, institutional exposure, <strong>and</strong> organisational embedding, <strong>and</strong> further<br />

evolve <strong>and</strong> contextualise them within the framework. Moreover, we identify the<br />

elements <strong>of</strong> our research object's embedding capabilities <strong>and</strong> how these contribute<br />

to value creation, respectively inhibit value destruction.<br />

Chapter five empirically substantiates the research framework by illustration <strong>of</strong> our<br />

three case studies <strong>and</strong> numerous embedded cases along the framework's<br />

dimensions. <strong>The</strong> case-by-case reflection is followed by a cross-case analysis, in<br />

which we identify relevant similarities <strong>and</strong> differences between the cases.<br />

Ultimately, the sixth <strong>and</strong> last chapter presents the results <strong>of</strong> this study, elucidates<br />

their practical <strong>and</strong> theoretical implications, <strong>and</strong> refers to the limitations <strong>and</strong><br />

directions for future research.<br />

<strong>The</strong> outline <strong>of</strong> this dissertation is summarized in the following Figure 1-4.


Introduction 13<br />

Outline<br />

1. Introduction<br />

Research problem <strong>and</strong> research gaps<br />

Research objective <strong>and</strong> guiding questions<br />

Key results <strong>and</strong> contribution<br />

2. <strong>The</strong>oretical embedding <strong>and</strong> literature review<br />

Strategic management research<br />

Economic geography, (new) institutionalism <strong>and</strong> economic sociology<br />

Value creation<br />

3. Empirical approach<br />

Research paradigm <strong>and</strong> research perspective<br />

Research methodology <strong>and</strong> design<br />

Research process <strong>and</strong> quality<br />

4. <strong>The</strong>ory building<br />

Development <strong>of</strong> research framework <strong>and</strong> propositions from a single-site & multi-site perspective<br />

Conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> location fixity <strong>and</strong> institutional exposure<br />

Embedding capabilities <strong>of</strong> the local firm - social <strong>and</strong> structural<br />

Value creation from a single-site <strong>and</strong> multi-site perspective<br />

5. Case studies<br />

Case-by-case analysis <strong>of</strong> three case objects<br />

Cross-case comparison to identify relevant commonalities/differences between the objects<br />

6. Discussion <strong>of</strong> results <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

Contribution to theory <strong>and</strong> practice<br />

Limitations <strong>and</strong> further research directions<br />

Final conclusions<br />

Figure 1-4: Outline <strong>of</strong> dissertation


14<br />

2 <strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

Our research subject <strong>and</strong> the related research questions have led us to identify three<br />

decisive constructs for theoretical orientation <strong>and</strong> choice <strong>of</strong> research lenses: locationfixity,<br />

organisational embeddedness, <strong>and</strong> value creation. For a theoretical grounding <strong>of</strong><br />

these (<strong>and</strong> related) constructs <strong>and</strong> for better orientation across the relevant fields <strong>of</strong><br />

research, we will therefore discuss the fields <strong>of</strong> strategic management research,<br />

economic geography, institutionalism, <strong>and</strong> economic sociology in the present chapter. In<br />

this context we will provide a brief introduction to these research fields, their relevant<br />

concepts <strong>and</strong> common ground with regard to the research topic, <strong>and</strong> their relation to the<br />

research questions.<br />

Strategic<br />

Management (2.1)<br />

Resource-based view;<br />

Capability-based view;<br />

Relational view<br />

Concepts from<br />

transaction cost<br />

economics, originating<br />

from organisational<br />

economics<br />

Economic Geography<br />

(2.2)<br />

Institutionalism<br />

(2.3)<br />

Economic Sociology<br />

(2.4)<br />

<strong>Location</strong> theory New institutionalism New economic<br />

sociology<br />

New economic<br />

geography<br />

(cultural turn)<br />

New institutional<br />

economics<br />

Stakeholder theory Legitimacy theory<br />

Table 2-1: Overview on relevant theoretical streams <strong>and</strong> concepts<br />

2.1 Relevant concepts <strong>of</strong> strategic management research<br />

Strategic management research, as a part <strong>of</strong> organisation theory, encompasses a wide<br />

field <strong>of</strong> different research str<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> reflects significant intellectual diversity. <strong>The</strong> field<br />

is characterised by “amorphous boundaries <strong>and</strong> inherent pluralism” (Nag, Hambrick, &<br />

Chen, 2007), which allows for the simultaneous preoccupation with multiple research<br />

orientations, such as economics, sociology, marketing, or management. Among other<br />

things, strategic management involves the adaptation <strong>of</strong> the organisation to its business<br />

environment, whereby it “is expected continually to assess external <strong>and</strong> internal<br />

conditions” (Chaffee, 1985: 91) <strong>and</strong> creating “satisfactory alignments <strong>of</strong> environmental<br />

opportunities <strong>and</strong> risks, on the one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> organisational capabilities <strong>and</strong> resources,<br />

on the other” (R. Miles & Cameron, 1982: 14). Accordingly, we underst<strong>and</strong> the aim <strong>of</strong>


<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

strategic management research as to develop an explanation <strong>of</strong> firm performance by<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing the roles <strong>of</strong> external <strong>and</strong> internal environments, how firms position<br />

themselves <strong>and</strong> operate within these environments <strong>and</strong> by relating firm's competencies<br />

<strong>and</strong> advantages to opportunities within external environments.<br />

Among the most influential str<strong>and</strong>s <strong>of</strong> strategic management research are the resourcebased<br />

view (RBV), considering the firm's idiosyncratic bundle <strong>of</strong> resources as its basis<br />

for competitive advantage, <strong>and</strong> thereto related the capability-based view (CBV), which<br />

focuses on the firm's capabilities as a special type <strong>of</strong> embedded, non-transferable, <strong>and</strong><br />

firm-specific resource that enhance the productivity <strong>of</strong> the firm's other resources<br />

(Makadok, 2001). Less established within strategic management research the 'relational<br />

view' stresses the concepts <strong>of</strong> power, trust <strong>and</strong> legitimacy with regard to the firm's<br />

success (Branco & Rodrigues, 2006).<br />

<strong>The</strong>se three str<strong>and</strong>s <strong>of</strong> strategic management research have a particular relevance to our<br />

research subject, since location-fix resources <strong>and</strong> the firm's dependence thereon<br />

represent a key characteristic <strong>of</strong> our research object, the utility respectively concession-<br />

based firm (UCF). It is therefore essential, how the firm is able to act under condition <strong>of</strong><br />

such dependence in order to remain competitive <strong>and</strong> successful in the long-term.<br />

Importantly, as a result <strong>of</strong> its close interconnectedness with the local environment, its<br />

intangible resources such as reputation <strong>and</strong> trust gain in relevance in order to become<br />

locally embedded <strong>and</strong> accepted by its stakeholders. <strong>The</strong>se aspects are more closely in<br />

the focus <strong>of</strong> the relational view, which constitutes a theoretical link towards the more<br />

contextual research lenses <strong>of</strong> institutionalism <strong>and</strong> economic sociology.<br />

2.1.1 Resource-based view<br />

In the perspective <strong>of</strong> the RBV, strategy represents the art <strong>of</strong> creating value (Normann &<br />

Ramirez, 1993). It is a continuing search for rent (Bower, 1974), defined as return in<br />

excess <strong>of</strong> a resource owner's opportunity costs (Tollison, 1982), stemming from the<br />

organisation's resources <strong>and</strong> capabilities <strong>and</strong> being appropriable by the firm (Amit &<br />

Schoemaker, 1993). At the heart <strong>of</strong> the RBV lies the neoclassical view <strong>of</strong> the firm as<br />

input-combiner. Differences in firm performance may be explained by a firm's resource<br />

endowment, respectively by the firm's distinctive competence in making better use <strong>of</strong> its<br />

resources. <strong>The</strong>se resources we underst<strong>and</strong> to include - apart from tangible resources -<br />

also<br />

15


16<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

all items not appearing in the material reports (balance sheets) such as<br />

organisational culture, reputation, <strong>and</strong> internal control. (Carmeli, 2004: 112)<br />

Importantly, the RBV acknowledges the existence <strong>of</strong> persistent above average earnings,<br />

which may be achieved through one <strong>of</strong> the following circumstances (Mahoney &<br />

P<strong>and</strong>ian, 1992):<br />

- Ricardian rents which result from the ownership <strong>of</strong> a valuable resource that is<br />

scarce<br />

- Monopoly rents realisable where barriers to potential competition are high, e.g.<br />

by government protection<br />

- Schumpeterian rents originating from risk-taking under uncertainty<br />

- Rents due to firm-specific assets<br />

All <strong>of</strong> these rent types to some extent are applicable to the activities <strong>of</strong> UCF, which will<br />

be shown in chapter four.<br />

Within the RBV, as an inward-oriented view <strong>of</strong> strategic content-research, managers'<br />

attention is directed to the identification <strong>of</strong> inputs that are likely to generate rents.<br />

Depending on its access to resources <strong>and</strong> resource combination, the firm may be able to<br />

create sustainable rents, e.g. by establishing isolating mechanisms 5 that protect it from<br />

imitation <strong>and</strong> preserve its rent streams (Rumelt, 1984). A particular form <strong>of</strong> isolating<br />

mechanisms may be found in the notion <strong>of</strong> asset specificity (cf. 2.1.4), which represents<br />

a distinct link between the RBV <strong>and</strong> transaction-cost economics (TCE). Asset<br />

specificity enhances a firm's rent-creation if one factor increases the value in<br />

combination with a second factor, but does not impact the value <strong>of</strong> a third (Conner,<br />

1991). In contrast to the logic <strong>of</strong> TCE, the RBV considers such rent-creation achievable<br />

within the firm as a result <strong>of</strong> its resource-combining ability. Since specific assets are<br />

difficult to trade, due to their strong tacit dimension <strong>and</strong> social complexity, their<br />

accumulation within the firm defies imitation, thus allowing for the creation <strong>of</strong><br />

sustainable rents (Dierickx & Cool, 1989).<br />

5 Typical isolating mechanisms include causal ambiguity, path dependency, cost to imitation, <strong>and</strong> legal<br />

barriers such as property rights to scarce resources, which for example utilities <strong>and</strong> extractive industries<br />

frequently rely upon.


<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

<strong>The</strong> RBV <strong>of</strong>fers central notions for guidance throughout our research project, as well as<br />

for the grounding <strong>of</strong> our construct <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> the link to value creation. Its<br />

focus on the role <strong>of</strong> resources, including intangible <strong>and</strong> idiosyncratic resource-bundles,<br />

for the firm's long-term success provide a valuable perspective in looking at the<br />

particular issues for location-bound firms <strong>and</strong> in theorising the location-fixity construct.<br />

2.1.2 Capability-based view<br />

<strong>The</strong> capability-based view (CBV) is grounded within the rather static RBV representing<br />

a dynamising extension <strong>of</strong> the latter's concepts. In their seminal article 'Dynamic<br />

Capabilities <strong>and</strong> Strategic Management' Teece, Pisano <strong>and</strong> Shuen (1997) emphasised the<br />

significance <strong>of</strong> the firm's ability to develop new capabilities, shifting the focus from<br />

rent-generation through resources to the process <strong>of</strong> capability accumulation. In contrast<br />

to the RBV, which regards strategic advantage to originate before the company uses the<br />

resource, the CBV considers the resource combination <strong>and</strong> coordination after their<br />

integration into the company as essential. In order to underline this notion Barney &<br />

Clark (2007: 22) define resources as “a firm's 'fundamental' financial, physical,<br />

individual, <strong>and</strong> organisational capital attributes, while capabilities are those attributes <strong>of</strong><br />

a firm that enable it to exploit its resources in implementing strategies”. Capabilities<br />

generally may be defined as<br />

organisational embedded non-transferable firm-specific resources whose purpose is<br />

to improve the productivity <strong>of</strong> other resources. (Makadok, 2001: 389)<br />

<strong>The</strong>y develop over time through complex interactions among the firm's resources <strong>and</strong><br />

ensure strategic flexibility <strong>and</strong> protection for the firm's final product or services.<br />

Examples <strong>of</strong> such value-creating processes are product development, strategic decisionmaking,<br />

alliancing, knowledge creation, <strong>and</strong> capabilities transfer (Eisenhardt & Martin,<br />

2000). Effective patterns <strong>of</strong> dynamic capabilities depend on the level <strong>of</strong> market<br />

dynamism. In moderately dynamic environments <strong>and</strong> the context <strong>of</strong> stable industry<br />

structures, dynamic capabilities resemble the traditional conception <strong>of</strong> routines, whereas<br />

in high-velocity markets <strong>and</strong> hazy industry structures, dynamic capabilities take on a<br />

different character: “[t]hey are simple, experiential, unstable processes that rely on<br />

quickly created new knowledge <strong>and</strong> iterative execution to produce adaptive, but<br />

unpredictable outcomes” (Eisenhardt & Martin, 2000: 1106).<br />

Teece, Pisano, <strong>and</strong> Shuen (1997) cluster dynamic capabilities in three categories:<br />

processes, positions, <strong>and</strong> paths, which are the fundamental units <strong>of</strong> analysis <strong>of</strong> the CBV.<br />

17


18<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

In their view, the essence <strong>of</strong> dynamic capabilities <strong>and</strong> competitive advantage are<br />

explained by organisational processes, which are formed by the specific asset position<br />

<strong>and</strong> the resulting available paths for a firm. <strong>The</strong> focus lies on assets <strong>of</strong> strategic interest,<br />

for which no ready market exists. Implicitly, the authors herewith exclude fixed assets,<br />

such as plants <strong>and</strong> equipment which can be purchased <strong>of</strong>f-the-shelf <strong>and</strong> hence are no<br />

source <strong>of</strong> competitive advantage. On the other h<strong>and</strong> intangibles such as difficult-to-trade<br />

knowledge assets, reputational, <strong>and</strong> relational assets determine competitive advantage.<br />

Following this argumentation, we would also include specialised plant <strong>and</strong> equipment,<br />

idiosyncratic to the firm's specificities <strong>and</strong> entailing significant firm-specific knowledge,<br />

to represent assets <strong>of</strong> strategic interest. With regard to our research object, the notions <strong>of</strong><br />

the CBV have high relevance pertaining to the limited spatial flexibility <strong>of</strong> our research<br />

object. <strong>The</strong> specialised infrastructure, to which UCFs' are spatially bound in the long-<br />

term, which are idiosyncratic to a specific site <strong>and</strong> to the institutional environment <strong>of</strong> the<br />

firm, necessarily shift the focus <strong>of</strong> rent-creation on the firm's capabilities, since its<br />

dependency on tangible resources is mostly given. While the RBV explains the rent-<br />

generation opportunities for location-bound entities with regard to their preferred access<br />

to site-specific resources, the CBV provides the framework for analysis <strong>of</strong> the value<br />

creation on the basis <strong>of</strong> the firm's capabilities <strong>and</strong> know-how. Due to specific<br />

characteristics <strong>and</strong> impaired spatial flexibility <strong>of</strong> UCF we assume that their value<br />

creation opportunities mainly originate from their capabilities <strong>and</strong> knowledge, within a<br />

specific site <strong>and</strong> in particular in the exchange <strong>and</strong> cooperation between sites.<br />

2.1.3 Relational view<br />

<strong>The</strong> relational view on strategic management has formed in the late 1990s, grounded in<br />

Dyer & Singh's (1998) seminal article on 'cooperative strategy <strong>and</strong> sources <strong>of</strong> interorganisational<br />

competitive advantage'. <strong>The</strong> authors suggest that a firm's critical<br />

resources may span firm boundaries <strong>and</strong> may be embedded in inter-firm resources <strong>and</strong><br />

routines. <strong>The</strong> sources <strong>of</strong> inter-organisational competitive advantage thereby lie in the<br />

firm's (1) relation-specific assets, (2) knowledge-sharing routines, (3) complementary<br />

resources <strong>and</strong> capabilities, <strong>and</strong> (4) effective governance. <strong>The</strong>ir criticism <strong>of</strong> the RBV<br />

pertains to its disregard <strong>of</strong> the role that the firm's relationship with its environment plays<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> the “institutional rules <strong>and</strong> resources this environment provides, how firms<br />

themselves depend on them … <strong>and</strong> how they can create common resources“ (Moldaschl<br />

& Fischer, 2004: 129), perceiving the firm’s environment merely as a blind selection<br />

mechanism <strong>and</strong> source <strong>of</strong> competitive pressure. <strong>The</strong> proposed extended view therefore


<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

regards firms from a resource-based perspective as social actors who are embedded in<br />

society: the firm itself is seen as an institution which is involved in interaction with<br />

others. As in the CBV, intangible resources are seen as key determinants to a firm's<br />

success, but some <strong>of</strong> them stem “from complex interaction relationships <strong>of</strong> various<br />

social groups, organisations <strong>and</strong> individuals” (ibid.: 130), such as reputation, trust, <strong>and</strong><br />

organisational legitimacy. <strong>The</strong>se relational resources are contained in relational ties<br />

between a firm <strong>and</strong> its stakeholders, “proposed as a promising source <strong>of</strong> sustainable<br />

competitive advantage because they are asymmetrically distributed across firms,<br />

imperfectly mobile, difficult to imitate, <strong>and</strong> have no readily available substitutes” (D.<br />

Davis & Mentzer, 2008: 436). Since consumers, politics <strong>and</strong> society as a whole are<br />

providers <strong>of</strong> these important resources, the diligent management <strong>of</strong> the exchange<br />

relationships with the environment gains in significance. By propagating such a theory<br />

<strong>of</strong> the embedded firm, the relational view within strategic management research<br />

establishes a strong link to institutional theories, borrowing thereto related socioeconomic<br />

concepts.<br />

<strong>The</strong> relational view <strong>and</strong> the related concepts from the RBV <strong>and</strong> institutional theory<br />

reflect our own multi-lens approach to the research question. Since UCFs are tied to<br />

their location, their relationship with the immediate environment becomes a critical<br />

success factor, in view <strong>of</strong> the visibility <strong>and</strong> the economic importance <strong>of</strong> their activities.<br />

In the analysis <strong>of</strong> the relationship between the location-fixed firm <strong>and</strong> its institutional<br />

environment, as well as the factors that support it in its value-creation endeavours, the<br />

notions <strong>of</strong> the relational view are an important source <strong>of</strong> theoretical inspiration <strong>and</strong><br />

grounding.<br />

2.1.4 Transaction cost economics<br />

Transaction cost economics (TCE) are theoretically attributed to the field <strong>of</strong><br />

organisational economics, which substantively overlaps with the resource-based view <strong>of</strong><br />

the firm <strong>and</strong> also has methodological similarities (Mahoney & P<strong>and</strong>ian, 1992). <strong>The</strong><br />

theoretical foundation to transaction cost economics has been laid by the institutional<br />

economist John R. Commons (1931) who started to view the economic interactions<br />

between individuals as transactions, <strong>and</strong> by Ronald Coase (1937: 21) who hypothesised<br />

that “the main reason why it is pr<strong>of</strong>itable to establish a firm would seem to be that there<br />

is a cost <strong>of</strong> using the price mechanism”. <strong>The</strong> subsequently developed theoretical<br />

framework takes the transaction as unit <strong>of</strong> analysis, being concerned with the various<br />

mechanisms for managing relationships between firms. In the 1970s, Oliver E.<br />

19


20<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

Williamson (1975) complemented the initial dichotomy <strong>of</strong> markets <strong>and</strong> firms with the<br />

possibility <strong>of</strong> firm cooperation <strong>and</strong> adapted the concepts to cover modern organisational<br />

forms. According to Williamson (1985a), transaction costs are determined through the<br />

frequency with which transactions occur, the degree <strong>of</strong> uncertainty to which they are<br />

subject, the condition <strong>of</strong> asset specificity, <strong>and</strong> the parties' bounded rationality <strong>and</strong><br />

opportunistic behaviour. <strong>The</strong> next two paragraphs will briefly touch upon the concepts<br />

<strong>of</strong> asset specificity <strong>and</strong> opportunism, which are <strong>of</strong> particular relevance for our research<br />

subject.<br />

Asset specificity. Within TCE the notion <strong>of</strong> asset specificity is among the constituting<br />

factors to the existence <strong>of</strong> firms, describing the degree to which an asset can be<br />

redeployed to alternative uses <strong>and</strong> by alternative users without sacrifice <strong>of</strong> productive<br />

value (OE Williamson, 1983). In this sense, asset-specific investments are characterised<br />

as unique, idiosyncratic, specific, or non-redeployable (Lohtia, Brooks, & Krapfel,<br />

1994). Asset specificity constitutes a central link between TCE <strong>and</strong> the RBV, albeit their<br />

significantly differing interpretations: while the RBV uses the concept with regard to the<br />

creation <strong>of</strong> value, respectively rent, TCE's theorising is directed at the avoidance <strong>of</strong> the<br />

(negative) effects <strong>of</strong> opportunism (Conner, 1991). Transaction-cost economics (OE<br />

Williamson, 1983, 1991) distinguishes six dimensions <strong>of</strong> asset specificity: (1) site<br />

specificity, caused by assets which are highly immobile <strong>and</strong> movable only at great cost,<br />

e.g. through a natural resource only available at a certain location; (2) physical asset<br />

specificity, where transacting parties make investments in equipment <strong>and</strong> machinery<br />

designed for a single purpose (the transaction) <strong>and</strong> which have lower values in<br />

alternative uses; (3) human asset specificity, such as through the dependence on highly<br />

specialised human skills; (4) dedicated assets, in the sense <strong>of</strong> a discrete investment in a<br />

plant that loses value, if employed in alternative uses <strong>and</strong> where premature termination<br />

<strong>of</strong> the contract would leave the supplier with significant excess capacity; (5) br<strong>and</strong><br />

name capital, through investments in reputation; <strong>and</strong> (6) temporal specificity, signifying<br />

a type <strong>of</strong> site specificity where timely responses from on-site human assets are critical.<br />

<strong>The</strong> notion <strong>of</strong> asset-specificity relates to transactions between actors resulting in a<br />

bilateral dependency as the parties' asset specificity deepens.


<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

Particularly two types <strong>of</strong> specificity are relevant to our research subject, namely site<br />

specificity <strong>and</strong> dedicated assets. As infrastructure-heavy organisations, UCFs bind<br />

significant capital in specialised, immobile infrastructure <strong>and</strong> equipment. Such sunk cost<br />

commitments not only tie them to their assets <strong>and</strong> location, but also expose them to their<br />

various local stakeholders, who - if acting opportunistically - could take advantage <strong>of</strong><br />

this dependence to renegotiate contracts over time. We therefore have further immersed<br />

in the literature <strong>of</strong> TCE throughout the development <strong>of</strong> our framework <strong>and</strong> will revert to<br />

the relevant concepts <strong>and</strong> notions in chapter 4.<br />

Opportunism. Another central notion <strong>of</strong> TCE is the assumption that economic actors<br />

seek to maximise their utility. In this context the ‘principal-agent’ problem requires<br />

mentioning, which refers to behavioural difficulties under conditions <strong>of</strong> incomplete <strong>and</strong><br />

asymmetric information, <strong>and</strong> the related problems <strong>of</strong> contracting under uncertainty.<br />

<strong>The</strong>reby problems <strong>of</strong> opportunism <strong>and</strong> moral hazard, as well as conflicts <strong>of</strong> interest may<br />

arise, either because one party has greater expertise or knowledge than the other, or<br />

because one party cannot directly observe the other’s actions.<br />

Pertaining to our research subject, in which the dependency <strong>of</strong> the UCF on its local<br />

environment <strong>and</strong> stakeholders plays a major role, such problems <strong>of</strong> contracting,<br />

opportunism, <strong>and</strong> power imbalances are important factors in the development <strong>of</strong> our<br />

research framework.<br />

2.1.5 Stakeholder theory<br />

Social responsibility <strong>of</strong> firms <strong>and</strong> moral values were first addressed within strategic<br />

management research by Igor Ans<strong>of</strong>f (1965: 65), who described personal non-economic<br />

objectives to “include philanthropy, personal ethics, social responsibilities, social status<br />

<strong>and</strong> reputation”. This element was further taken up by Kenneth Andrews (1971),<br />

stipulating strategy to consist <strong>of</strong> four elements, such as (1) market opportunity, (2)<br />

corporate competence <strong>and</strong> resources, (3) personal values <strong>and</strong> aspirations, <strong>and</strong> (4)<br />

acknowledged obligations to groups other than shareholders. Consequently, decisions<br />

for the most suitable strategy <strong>of</strong> a firm to follow cannot be isolated from the personal<br />

values <strong>of</strong> the decision makers <strong>and</strong> should pay attention to social issues. This subjectivist<br />

view <strong>of</strong> ethics, characteristic throughout the 1960s, considered ethical firm comportment<br />

as a matter <strong>of</strong> goodwill <strong>of</strong> the firm's leadership, relying on their personal moral values<br />

(Simon, 1961). Thus reduced to personal preferences, ethics is kept outside the<br />

21


22<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

rationality <strong>of</strong> the decision. On the basis <strong>of</strong> this view, strategic management theory<br />

therefore for considerable time has not seriously attempted to integrate the normative<br />

ethical principles into its field (Melé & Guillén, 2006).<br />

In the 1970s however, the scientific discussion <strong>of</strong> social responsibilities led to the<br />

linking <strong>of</strong> corporate social responsibility (CSR) <strong>and</strong> strategy, <strong>and</strong> to addressing the risks<br />

that a firm assumes if its behaviour runs counter to the expectations <strong>of</strong> its social<br />

environment (K. Davis, 1975). A number <strong>of</strong> theories began to form, addressing the<br />

firm's response to these expectations <strong>and</strong> the role <strong>of</strong> social legitimacy as a source <strong>of</strong><br />

competitive advantage. In the late 1970s stakeholder theory emerged out <strong>of</strong> these<br />

considerations, most noticeably advanced by Dill (1975), Freeman & Reed (1983); <strong>and</strong><br />

more recently by Clarkson (1994; 1995); Mitchell, Agle, & Wood (1997); Phillips<br />

(2003); <strong>and</strong> Post, Preston, & Sachs (Post et al., 2002a; 2002b), just to name a few. <strong>The</strong><br />

integration <strong>of</strong> the stakeholder view into the thinking <strong>of</strong> strategic management becomes<br />

particularly evident in Freeman's (1984: 46) definition <strong>of</strong> stakeholders as “any group or<br />

individual who can affect or is affected by the achievement <strong>of</strong> an organisation's<br />

objectives”. Since the key notions <strong>and</strong> concepts <strong>of</strong> stakeholder theory will be further<br />

reviewed in chapter 4.6.1, we will not further detail them in the present review <strong>of</strong><br />

literature.<br />

<strong>The</strong> relevance <strong>of</strong> stakeholder theory for our research is linked with the notion <strong>of</strong><br />

organisational embeddedness, central to the developed research framework, <strong>and</strong> is<br />

founded in the high importance <strong>of</strong> UCFs' relations with their local environment. <strong>The</strong><br />

legitimacy <strong>of</strong> a firm within this environment is considered as an important resource for<br />

the firm's value creation opportunities. Within our framework we follow the stakeholder<br />

conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> Phillips (2003), who identifies normative <strong>and</strong> derivative<br />

stakeholders in order to help the firm distinguish between a stakeholder relationship<br />

based on direct moral obligation <strong>and</strong> one based on the power to help or harm the firm.<br />

Both stakeholder groups have legitimacy to the firm, but both legitimacies are<br />

importantly different. Phillips defines normative stakeholders as those, for whose<br />

benefit the firm should be managed, whereas derivative stakeholders are “those groups<br />

whose actions <strong>and</strong> claims must be accounted for by managers due to their potential<br />

effects upon the organisation <strong>and</strong> its normative stakeholders” (ibid.: 31). We have drawn<br />

on these definitions throughout the development <strong>of</strong> our research framework.


<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

2.2 Relevant concepts <strong>of</strong> economic geography<br />

<strong>The</strong> key concepts <strong>of</strong> economic geography, very generally, are space (referring to<br />

physical distance <strong>and</strong> area), place (capturing the specificity <strong>of</strong> a particular location out<br />

<strong>of</strong> space) <strong>and</strong> scale (organising places through a typology <strong>of</strong> spatial scales) (Coe, Kelly,<br />

& Yeung, 2007). Its ideas come from a number <strong>of</strong> related fields, including economics,<br />

sociology, psychology <strong>and</strong> management science, with which it shares occasionally<br />

blurred boundaries. Its interface function therefore makes it particularly suitable to<br />

integrate, link <strong>and</strong> further develop the insights, concepts <strong>and</strong> methods <strong>of</strong> these different<br />

fields in a way which contributes to a consolidation <strong>of</strong> the current level <strong>of</strong> knowledge<br />

(Zademach, 2002). In the past four decades economic geography has undergone a<br />

significant transformation <strong>and</strong>, since the 1980s, even a radical restructuring, shifting<br />

from universalising location theory <strong>and</strong> developing geographically specific theories <strong>of</strong><br />

territorial development “to the more reflexive cultural turn that champions heightened<br />

sensitivity to the positionality <strong>of</strong> knowledge <strong>and</strong> theories <strong>and</strong> the context in which these<br />

theories emerge” (Yeung & Lin, 2003: 115). While its initial conceptualisations<br />

neglected behavioural aspects <strong>of</strong> economic actors, in the past decade a fuller<br />

conceptualisation emerged which considers social, cultural, institutional <strong>and</strong> political<br />

aspects <strong>of</strong> human agency (Bathelt & Glueckler, 2003). <strong>The</strong>reby it draws - among others<br />

- on institutionalist views <strong>of</strong> the firm <strong>and</strong> on network perspectives, viewing the firm as<br />

“embedded in socially constructed networks <strong>of</strong> reciprocity <strong>and</strong> interdependence” (M.<br />

Taylor & Asheim, 2001: 316).<br />

Research in economic geography usually is concerned with the perspective <strong>of</strong> a wider<br />

(geographic) scale <strong>and</strong> has no strong tradition <strong>of</strong> studying economic phenomena at the<br />

firm-level (Oinas, 1997). However, as business economics' view <strong>of</strong> the firm tends to<br />

underplay “the dynamic role <strong>of</strong> place, space, <strong>and</strong> spatiality in shaping firms' operations”<br />

(M. Taylor & Asheim, 2001: 324), the interface function <strong>of</strong> economic geography is<br />

ideally suited as a platform for trying out new ideas. <strong>The</strong> leading theoretical<br />

perspectives <strong>of</strong> economic geography are illustrated in Table 2-2.<br />

23


24<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical perspective Emergence Substantive research issues<br />

<strong>Location</strong> theory (neo-classical) 1950s patterns in the distribution <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

activities across space<br />

Behavioural approach late 1960s alternative behavioural models to homo<br />

economicus; influencing factors on<br />

economic decision-making in various<br />

situations<br />

Structuralist approach 1970s social relations <strong>and</strong> economic structures <strong>of</strong><br />

capitalist economies<br />

Post-structuralist approach /<br />

cultural turn<br />

Table 2-2: <strong>The</strong>oretical perspectives in economic geography 6<br />

1990s embeddedness <strong>of</strong> economic action <strong>and</strong><br />

behaviour in social, cultural <strong>and</strong> political<br />

context; specific <strong>and</strong> place-specific features<br />

<strong>of</strong> societies <strong>and</strong> economies<br />

Due to their relevance for our research subject, we will briefly outline the perspectives<br />

<strong>of</strong> location theory <strong>and</strong> the post-structuralist approach, which is closely interlinked with<br />

concepts from institutionalism <strong>and</strong> (economic) sociology.<br />

2.2.1 <strong>Location</strong> theory<br />

Tracing back to Johann Heinrich von Thuenen's first volume <strong>of</strong> 'Der Isolierte Staat'<br />

(1826) location theory essentially addresses the question <strong>of</strong> economic players' spatial<br />

relatedness. <strong>The</strong>reby it aims at underst<strong>and</strong>ing the “role <strong>of</strong> space <strong>and</strong> place in shaping<br />

economic activity <strong>and</strong> performance (<strong>and</strong> vice versa), whether they are based on<br />

individual economic actors, firms, industries, markets or regional <strong>and</strong> global<br />

economies” (Yeung, 2001: 172). Furthermore, location theory is concerned with the<br />

impact <strong>of</strong> transportation cost on locational decisions, distinguishing between resource<br />

(or input) orientation <strong>and</strong> market (or output) orientation <strong>of</strong> the firm, which is decided on<br />

the basis <strong>of</strong> whichever <strong>of</strong> the two is costlier to move.<br />

<strong>Local</strong> dependence. Firms naturally interact with their local environment in order to<br />

maintain their functionality. <strong>The</strong>ir links to the locality persist for example through the<br />

local labour market, supplier networks, or consumer markets. <strong>The</strong>se localised linkages<br />

<strong>of</strong> firms are rarely stable as a consequence <strong>of</strong> their search for pr<strong>of</strong>it <strong>and</strong> more rentgenerating<br />

ways <strong>of</strong> production, which may entail also spatial restructuring <strong>and</strong> complete<br />

relocation. However, under certain circumstances adjustments to a new geography<br />

6 On the basis <strong>of</strong> Coe et al., 2007.


<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

might be more difficult <strong>and</strong> relocation might result in high opportunity cost <strong>and</strong> loss <strong>of</strong><br />

competitive edge (Cox & Mair, 1988), rendering the firm location-dependent. Such<br />

local dependence is characterised by Oinas (1998) as the firm's dependence on a<br />

resource which is critical to its operation <strong>and</strong> to which it needs access as a necessary<br />

condition for its operation. From a more socio-economic perspective Cox <strong>and</strong> Mair<br />

(1988: 307) propose a relational view by defining it as “the dependence <strong>of</strong> various<br />

actors - capitalist firms, politicians, people - on the reproduction <strong>of</strong> certain social<br />

relations within a particular territory”. Thus, the firm's spatial immobility may stem<br />

from sunk costs 7 , e.g. in the form <strong>of</strong> highly capital-intensive assets which result in<br />

locked-up value; linkages with local actors, such as critical long-term supplier or<br />

customer relationships or non-substitutable relations with government <strong>of</strong>ficials; or a<br />

dependence on locality-specific resources. According to Oinas (1998) resources are<br />

locality-specific if they cannot be obtained from other localities, <strong>and</strong> if they are either<br />

non-transferable or controlled by other locally dependent actors who are not willing to<br />

relocate themselves nor the resource.<br />

Conceptual link to the RBV. Thus, considering local dependence 8 as a form <strong>of</strong><br />

resource dependence, on a set <strong>of</strong> locality-specific resources or on the locality as a whole,<br />

location theory shares an important link to the resource-based view. <strong>The</strong>reby the effects<br />

<strong>of</strong> a firm's asset specificity more or less correspond with the effects <strong>of</strong> local dependence,<br />

since a firm's human asset specificity, site specificity <strong>and</strong> dedicated assets tie it to a<br />

specific location <strong>and</strong> tend to make it spatially immobile.<br />

<strong>Location</strong> theory assumes relevance within our research subject due to its<br />

conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> space, the determinants <strong>of</strong> firms' location decisions, <strong>and</strong> thereto<br />

related <strong>of</strong> their location dependence. <strong>The</strong>se notions <strong>and</strong> location theory's links with the<br />

resource-based perspective have been important in our underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the<br />

characteristics <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> the latter's effects on the firm, respectively on the<br />

firm's value-creation opportunities.<br />

7<br />

Mata (1991: 52) defines sunk costs as those "costs <strong>of</strong> a firm which are irrevocably committed to a<br />

particular use, <strong>and</strong> therefore are not recoverable in case <strong>of</strong> exit".<br />

8<br />

While Oinas (1998) defines local dependence as the firm's dependence on a resource which is critical<br />

to its operation <strong>and</strong> to which it needs access as a necessary condition for its operation, Cox & Mair<br />

(1988: 307) propose a more socialised view by defining it as "the dependence <strong>of</strong> various actors -<br />

capitalist firms, politicians, people - on the reproduction <strong>of</strong> certain social relations within a particular<br />

territory".<br />

25


26<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

2.2.2 New economic geography - the cultural turn<br />

Traditionally, economic geography abstracted economic action from its social, political,<br />

<strong>and</strong> cultural context, but in recent years it has been acknowledged that economic activity<br />

is socially <strong>and</strong> institutionally situated, being “understood as enmeshed in wider<br />

structures <strong>of</strong> social, economic, <strong>and</strong> political rules, procedures <strong>and</strong> conventions” (R.<br />

Martin, 2003: 79), affecting the decisions <strong>of</strong> economic actors. <strong>The</strong> related new<br />

theorising efforts have led to additional insights on firms' local embeddedness <strong>and</strong> local<br />

dependence <strong>and</strong> to the establishment <strong>of</strong> the related research stream <strong>of</strong> 'new economic<br />

geography' 9 . Moving away from the simple neo-classical assumption <strong>of</strong> the homo<br />

economicus, it explores a wider range <strong>of</strong> goals <strong>and</strong> preferences <strong>of</strong> human action,<br />

considering economic life is an instituted process <strong>and</strong> a socially embedded activity,<br />

which is context-specific <strong>and</strong> path-dependent (Amin, 2004).<br />

<strong>Local</strong> embeddedness. Drawing on the field <strong>of</strong> institutionalism, the concept <strong>of</strong><br />

embeddedness has become a central notion <strong>of</strong> new economic geography. Embeddedness<br />

entails<br />

the way in which organisations or actors become tied in to the local business <strong>and</strong><br />

institutional environment. (Alderman, 2004: 256)<br />

It goes beyond a merely geographical connotation, rather being<br />

defined by reciprocal, social, political <strong>and</strong> economic processes that occur at multiple<br />

scales <strong>and</strong> change constantly at any given scale. (Hayter, 2004: 99)<br />

Such embeddedness may include the firm's dependence on a particular local product,<br />

service <strong>and</strong> labour market, but also on local government jurisdiction, or the growth <strong>of</strong><br />

the local economy (Cox, 1998a). On a political dimension it refers “to the involvement<br />

<strong>of</strong> economic actors in local political practices conditioned by relations <strong>of</strong> dependence<br />

<strong>and</strong> power” (Oinas, 1998: 124). Consequently, the region, respectively the local<br />

environment <strong>of</strong> the firm <strong>and</strong> its relations thereto are considered as important factors for<br />

the firm's sustained livelihood <strong>and</strong> competitiveness. <strong>The</strong> question how embeddedness to<br />

its local environment affects the firm's performance <strong>and</strong> operation therefore has been the<br />

subject <strong>of</strong> a number <strong>of</strong> publications in economic geography (e.g. Hayter, 2004; Oinas,<br />

1999b).<br />

9 New economic geography, which refers to the study <strong>of</strong> economic activities in relation to other<br />

political, social, cultural, <strong>and</strong> institutional processes in society <strong>and</strong> space, should not be confused with<br />

the economic approach <strong>of</strong> 'New Economic Geography', which aims at reintroducing spatial analysis into<br />

mainstream equilibrium models <strong>and</strong> is most prominently represented by the research <strong>of</strong> Paul Krugman<br />

(e.g. Krugman, 1998).


<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

<strong>The</strong> relational view within economic geography, in particular the notion <strong>of</strong><br />

embeddedness, has been integrated <strong>and</strong> conceptually refined in our research framework<br />

pertaining to our research object, utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based firms. <strong>The</strong> thereto<br />

related aspects <strong>of</strong> power <strong>and</strong> dependence are important in view <strong>of</strong> the high regulatory<br />

density <strong>of</strong> our research object, <strong>and</strong> their strategic relevance for the local economy as<br />

well as their high visibility due to their externalities (see also chapter 4).<br />

2.3 Relevant concepts <strong>of</strong> (new) institutionalism<br />

<strong>The</strong> core ideas <strong>of</strong> institutionalism relate to institutions, habits, rules, <strong>and</strong> their evolution.<br />

Thus, institutional theory is concerned - inter alia - with the relations between the firm<br />

<strong>and</strong> its environment <strong>and</strong> the ways in which firms react to institutional processes,<br />

respectively which roles institutions play in shaping economic behaviour. In this context<br />

institutions are understood as “the rules <strong>of</strong> the game in society or, more formally, ... the<br />

humanly devised constraints that shape human interaction” (North, 1990: 3). As such<br />

the role <strong>of</strong> institutions<br />

is to provide stability in the real economic context <strong>of</strong> information asymmetry, market<br />

uncertainty <strong>and</strong> knowledge boundedness, by restricting the field <strong>of</strong> possibilities<br />

available, garnering consensus <strong>and</strong> common underst<strong>and</strong>ings <strong>and</strong> guiding individual<br />

action. (Amin, 2004: 367)<br />

However, while they reduce uncertainty in human exchange, institutions simultaneously<br />

also prescribe <strong>and</strong> in some ways constrain the future development <strong>of</strong> the economic<br />

actors.<br />

New institutionalism refers to the collection <strong>of</strong> schools <strong>of</strong> thought that seek to explain<br />

political, historical, economic <strong>and</strong> social institutions such as government, law, markets,<br />

firms, social conventions, etc. in terms <strong>of</strong> concepts from neoclassical economics. Its<br />

main proponents include Ronald Coase, Armen Alchian, Harold Demsetz <strong>and</strong> Oliver E.<br />

Williamson, who significantly advanced the theoretical maturity <strong>of</strong> the transaction costs<br />

<strong>and</strong> the property rights paradigm. Within organisation studies new institutionalism has<br />

effected a shift <strong>of</strong> focus, comprising<br />

a rejection <strong>of</strong> rational-actor models, an interest in institutions as independent<br />

variables, a turn toward cognitive <strong>and</strong> cultural explanations, <strong>and</strong> an interest in<br />

properties <strong>of</strong> supraindividual units <strong>of</strong> analysis that cannot be reduced to<br />

aggregations or direct consequences <strong>of</strong> individuals' attributes or motives. (DiMaggio<br />

& Powell, 1991: 8)<br />

27


28<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

Thus, the rejection <strong>of</strong> the neoclassical tendency to isolate a purely economic sphere<br />

(Mjøset, 1985) has led to the application <strong>of</strong> a more socio-economic lens where “markets<br />

are socially constructed; economics are diachronic, evolutionary, <strong>and</strong> volatile; <strong>and</strong><br />

economic behaviour is itself embedded in a <strong>and</strong> shaped through a whole range <strong>of</strong><br />

institutional habits … <strong>and</strong> place-based ties <strong>of</strong> proximity” (McLeod, 2004: 59).<br />

2.3.1 New institutional economics<br />

At the heart <strong>of</strong> new institutional economics (NIE) is the postulate that institutions matter<br />

for economic performance. Consequently, NIE studies institutions <strong>and</strong> how these<br />

interact with organisations, focusing on “an interdisciplinary combination <strong>of</strong> law,<br />

economics, <strong>and</strong> organisation in which economics is the first among equals” (OE<br />

Williamson, 1996: 3). It builds on neoclassical theory, modifies <strong>and</strong> extends it, thus<br />

coming to terms with a number <strong>of</strong> hitherto unresolved issues (North, 1992): contrary to<br />

the neoclassical paradigm NIE assumes that individuals have incomplete information,<br />

that their decisions are prone to bounded rationality, that they consequently face<br />

uncertainty <strong>and</strong> incur transaction costs through their information gathering. As a means<br />

to reduce such uncertainty formal <strong>and</strong> informal institutions are created, developing<br />

modes <strong>of</strong> organisation embedded in our society (Ménard & Shirley, 2005). Importantly<br />

also, NIE adheres to the concept <strong>of</strong> methodological individualism, which attributes an<br />

entirely new role to individual decision makers, seeing 'society', 'the state' or 'the firm'<br />

not as collective, but rather as consisting <strong>of</strong> individually acting agents (Furubotn &<br />

Richter, 2005). Consequently, it focuses on the responsive <strong>and</strong> problem-solving<br />

behaviour <strong>of</strong> individuals who produce the phenomena <strong>of</strong> interest.<br />

Economic <strong>and</strong> political interaction. Importantly, institutional economics addresses<br />

also the interaction between economic <strong>and</strong> political markets, <strong>and</strong> what impacts the<br />

polity has on transactional environments. <strong>The</strong>reby it abolishes the traditional economic<br />

perception <strong>of</strong> government being either a leviathan or entirely benevolent, rather turning<br />

towards the way in which institutional arrangement can affect governmental incentives<br />

<strong>and</strong> performance (Ménard & Shirley). In this discussion, trust in the government plays a<br />

central role: a trustworthy government keeps its promises <strong>and</strong> acts in the interest <strong>of</strong> its<br />

citizens. Its institutions ensure fair procedures <strong>and</strong> improve mutual trust between<br />

government <strong>and</strong> citizens. <strong>The</strong> credibility <strong>of</strong> the government's commitments therefore has<br />

a significant impact on economic activity <strong>and</strong> firm behaviour.<br />

Social element in economic activity. Economic institutionalists have found a vehicle to<br />

introduce a contextual <strong>and</strong> culturally sensitive interpretation <strong>of</strong> economic activity: the<br />

institutions, whose actions “are embedded within, <strong>and</strong> constrained by, a local


<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

institutional culture <strong>of</strong> social relations, tacit rules <strong>and</strong> formal regulations” (Barnes &<br />

Gertler, 1999: xviii, as cited in McLeod, 2004: 62). <strong>The</strong>reby the social element is<br />

attributed not merely a regulatory but a constitutive function in the economy.<br />

Consequently, from an institutional view the creation <strong>of</strong> value <strong>and</strong> competitive<br />

advantage is considered to be related to the processes <strong>of</strong> perception, deliberation <strong>and</strong> the<br />

firm's responsiveness <strong>and</strong> capacity for adaptation (Litz, 1996), as well as the firm's<br />

ability to build sustainable relationships with its key stakeholders.<br />

Modes <strong>of</strong> governance. In addition to the institutional environment, NIE also is<br />

concerned with microanalytic issues such as the institutions <strong>of</strong> governance, which take<br />

the transaction as unit <strong>of</strong> analysis (OE Williamson, 1996). On this level <strong>of</strong> analysis the<br />

institutional environment specifies the relevant setting respectively constraints. Based<br />

on the assumptions <strong>of</strong> transaction cost theory, in particular bounded rationality <strong>and</strong><br />

opportunism, NIE studies questions related to incomplete contracting <strong>and</strong> analyses the<br />

possibilities to identify, explicate, <strong>and</strong> mitigate contractual hazards. <strong>The</strong>se hazards<br />

include bilateral dependence, weak property rights, hazards <strong>of</strong> measurement, intertemporal<br />

hazards, <strong>and</strong> the hazards <strong>of</strong> a weak institutional environment (ibid.). Effective<br />

government modes become increasingly essential, thus, the more asset- <strong>and</strong><br />

relationship-specific investments are made. In addition complex contracts are prone to<br />

maladaptation over time, further exposing the parties to uncertainty <strong>and</strong> risk <strong>of</strong><br />

renegotiation. To overcome these hazards, TCE therefore sees legal enforcement <strong>and</strong><br />

self enforcement as complementing one another, with governance structures <strong>of</strong><br />

nonst<strong>and</strong>ard contractual relationships being characterised by court ordering <strong>and</strong> private<br />

ordering (Richter, 2001).<br />

For our research framework the literature on NIE has proven useful with regard to the<br />

firm's dependence on its public (in the sense <strong>of</strong> state-related) stakeholders. Since the<br />

(usually highly regulated) UCF commits itself over long periods <strong>of</strong> time to a location,<br />

being dependent on the state's regulatory regime, state-granted concessions <strong>and</strong> credible<br />

commitments with regard to the contractual arrangements with the state <strong>and</strong> property<br />

rights, the institutional economics provide the concepts <strong>and</strong> frameworks to address such<br />

issues.<br />

2.3.2 Legitimacy theory<br />

According to legitimacy theory, firms exist in society under an expressed or implicit<br />

social contract. <strong>The</strong> notion <strong>of</strong> legitimacy gives explicit consideration to the expectations<br />

<strong>of</strong> society. Its origins lie in political economy theory, while its concepts greatly overlap<br />

29


30<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

with institutional theory <strong>and</strong> stakeholder theory <strong>and</strong> are linked with notions from the<br />

resource-based perspective. In brief, organisational legitimacy is defined as the<br />

acceptance <strong>of</strong> the organisation by its environment. More precisely it “is a generalised<br />

perception or assumption that the actions <strong>of</strong> an entity are desirable, proper, or<br />

appropriate within some socially constructed system <strong>of</strong> norms, values, beliefs, <strong>and</strong><br />

definitions” (Suchman, 1995: 574). It represents a reaction <strong>of</strong> observers to the<br />

organisation as they perceive it, which is why “legitimacy is possessed objectively, yet<br />

created subjectively” (ibid.). Thus socially constructed, it depends on a collective<br />

audience <strong>and</strong> is time- <strong>and</strong> place-dependent. Importantly therefore, the conditions to<br />

attain organisational legitimacy may change over time, respectively may vary across<br />

different cultural <strong>and</strong> institutional environments. Accordingly, firms need to be aware <strong>of</strong><br />

society's expectations, values <strong>and</strong> any changes there<strong>of</strong> <strong>and</strong> consequently try to anticipate<br />

<strong>and</strong> adapt to them. Organisational legitimacy represents an important firm resource,<br />

since it affects the way that people act towards firms, “but also how they underst<strong>and</strong><br />

them. Thus, audiences perceive the legitimate organisation not only as more worthy, but<br />

also as more meaningful, more predictable. <strong>and</strong> more trustworthy” (ibid.: 575).<br />

While institutional research considers organisational legitimacy beyond the direct<br />

control <strong>of</strong> the firm, a strategic view stresses instrumental aspects, assuming a high level<br />

<strong>of</strong> managerial control over the legitimisation process. <strong>The</strong>reby legitimacy is seen as a<br />

resource for the firm on which it depends for its long-term success <strong>and</strong> survival.<br />

Within our research framework we agree with Suchman's (ibid.) view, that real-world<br />

firms encounter both kinds <strong>of</strong> challenges, strategic operational <strong>and</strong> institutional<br />

constitutive pressures. <strong>The</strong>refore we accept this duality <strong>and</strong> underst<strong>and</strong> organisational<br />

legitimacy as to include manipulable resource-like aspects <strong>and</strong> elements <strong>of</strong> a taken-for-<br />

granted belief system.<br />

2.4 Relevant concepts <strong>of</strong> economic sociology<br />

As does new institutional economics, economic sociology deals with social actions. In<br />

the classical fields <strong>of</strong> sociology <strong>and</strong> economics there are considerable differences with<br />

regard to the influence between individual actors. In sociology these actors are<br />

influenced by other actors, while in economics there is no such influence. Furthermore,<br />

there are opposing conceptualisations <strong>of</strong> human behaviour <strong>and</strong> motivations: while<br />

sociologists allow for various types <strong>of</strong> human action, which includes (boundedly)<br />

rational action, for economists there is only perfect rationality (Smelser & Swedberg,


<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

2005). As a response to new institutional economics' advance into sociologists’ territory,<br />

the latter responded to these new conceptualisations with the development <strong>of</strong> new<br />

economic sociology <strong>and</strong> the rediscovery <strong>of</strong> their old object <strong>of</strong> research, “institutions”<br />

(Richter, 2001) which resulted in the development <strong>of</strong> new institutionalism. In this<br />

process economic <strong>and</strong> sociological conceptualisations have become closely interrelated,<br />

with new economic sociology's theoretical approaches being fundamentally eclectic <strong>and</strong><br />

pluralistic <strong>and</strong> with no emerging dominant perspective.<br />

2.4.1 New economic sociology<br />

New economic sociology (NES) draws on concepts from organisation theory 10 in order<br />

to explore - among others - the links between the corporation <strong>and</strong> its environment.<br />

Phenomena like power or trust thereby constitute fundamental parts <strong>of</strong> the theoretical<br />

constructions, which look rather ad hoc to an economist. Richter (2001) identifies the<br />

following three assumptions as central to NES: (1) economic action as social action,<br />

whereby the<br />

[e]conomic relations between two parties can be <strong>of</strong> different character: implicit or<br />

explicit; hierarchical or among equals, mutually binding contractual relations with<br />

freely chosen partners (according to the principle <strong>of</strong> freedom <strong>of</strong> contract) or power<br />

relationships (dominance <strong>and</strong> compliance), reciprocal or one-sided, based on trust or<br />

burdened by distrust. (ibid.: 8);<br />

(2) embeddedness <strong>of</strong> social action, with social actions being constrained by ongoing<br />

social relations which are embedded in enduring networks <strong>of</strong> personal relationships; <strong>and</strong><br />

the assumption <strong>of</strong> the (3) social construction <strong>of</strong> economic institutions, in which real<br />

world institutions are not seen as results <strong>of</strong> a perfectly transparent market <strong>and</strong> purely<br />

rational choice, or the work <strong>of</strong> an invisible h<strong>and</strong>, but rather as mixtures <strong>of</strong> conflict <strong>and</strong><br />

coordination, <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> opposing <strong>and</strong> coinciding interests.<br />

Embeddedness. Based on the seminal work <strong>of</strong> Polanyi (1944), '<strong>The</strong> Great<br />

Transformation', <strong>and</strong> further conceptualisations by Granovetter (1985) the concept <strong>of</strong><br />

embeddedness has developed into a core concept <strong>of</strong> economic sociology. It builds on the<br />

argument that “[t]he [economic] behaviour <strong>and</strong> institutions to be analysed are so<br />

constrained by ongoing social relations that to construe them as independent is a<br />

grievous misunderst<strong>and</strong>ing” (Granovetter, 1985, as cited in Yeung, 2003: 482). In other<br />

words, Granovetter - critical <strong>of</strong> the economism underlying Williamson’s (1975)<br />

10<br />

Of particular relevance are the theoretical approaches <strong>of</strong> resource dependency, population ecology,<br />

<strong>and</strong> new institutionalism (see also Smelser & Swedberg, 2005).<br />

31


32<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

transaction cost model - defined embeddedness in terms <strong>of</strong> socially instituted processes<br />

created by reciprocal links between economic <strong>and</strong> social (noneconomic) institutions<br />

(Hayter, 2004). Importantly, organisational embeddedness builds on the notion that<br />

economic activity is organised through institutions, whereby the institutions themselves<br />

are anchored in wider political arrangements <strong>and</strong> cultural systems <strong>of</strong> meaning<br />

(Hamilton, 1994). Zukin <strong>and</strong> DiMaggio (1990) widened this conceptualisation,<br />

proposing that embeddedness refers to the contingent nature <strong>of</strong> economic activity with<br />

regard to four dimensions: cognition, culture, social structures, <strong>and</strong> political institutions.<br />

Accordingly they have developed a taxation <strong>of</strong> embeddedness, including (1) structural<br />

embeddedness, understood as “contextualisation <strong>of</strong> economic exchange in patterns <strong>of</strong><br />

ongoing interpersonal relations” (ibid.: 18); (2) cultural embeddedness, as “the ways<br />

shared underst<strong>and</strong>ings <strong>and</strong> meanings come to give form to organisation activity,<br />

structures, <strong>and</strong> process” (Dacin, Ventresca, & Beal, 1999: 328); (3) cognitive<br />

embeddedness, as the “ways in which the structured regularities <strong>of</strong> mental processes<br />

limit the exercise <strong>of</strong> economic reasoning” (Zukin & DiMaggio, 1990: 15f); <strong>and</strong> (4)<br />

political embeddedness, as the “manner in which economic institutions <strong>and</strong> decisions<br />

are shaped by a struggle for power that involves economic actors <strong>and</strong> nonmarket<br />

institutions, particularly the state <strong>and</strong> social classes” (ibid.: 22). Through this enhanced<br />

concept a number <strong>of</strong> ambiguities <strong>of</strong> the embeddedness term could be resolved, as will be<br />

further discussed in sub-chapter 4.8.<br />

For our research framework the notion <strong>of</strong> embeddedness has assumed high significance<br />

in overcoming the disadvantages <strong>of</strong> the firm's location-fixity for its value creation<br />

opportunities 11 . As will be further outlined in chapter 4, we have identified the firm's<br />

embedding capabilities as a moderating factor in the relationship between location-fixity<br />

<strong>and</strong> value creation. <strong>The</strong>reby the taxation <strong>of</strong> Zukin <strong>and</strong> DiMaggio has been useful<br />

towards enhancing the concept to reflect the particular characteristics <strong>of</strong> UCF.<br />

Furthermore, in accordance with Dacin, Ventresca, <strong>and</strong> Beal (1999) we underst<strong>and</strong><br />

embeddedness on one side to impose limits on what organisations can do, but also as to<br />

entail opportunities for firms.<br />

Trust <strong>and</strong> reciprocity. Contrary to the purely self-interested human conceptualisation <strong>of</strong><br />

economics <strong>and</strong> TCE, within NES trust <strong>and</strong> reciprocity are considered as basic motives<br />

11 According to Davis & Mentzer (2008), the theory <strong>of</strong> embeddedness accounts for the value derived<br />

from relational resources, thus establishing a link between the sociological / institutional concept <strong>and</strong> the<br />

resource-based view.


<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

<strong>of</strong> economic action besides self interest. Uzzi (1996: 677) claims “that embeddedness<br />

shifts actors’ motivations away from narrow pursuit <strong>of</strong> immediate economic gains<br />

toward the enrichment <strong>of</strong> relationships through trust <strong>and</strong> reciprocity”, whereby Fehr &<br />

Gächter (2000) distinguish between positive reciprocity to include all cooperative<br />

reciprocal tendencies, <strong>and</strong> negative reciprocity referring to retaliatory aspects.<br />

Importantly, reciprocity includes responses from actors to friendly or hostile actions<br />

even if no material gains can be expected. Furthermore, it is equally different from<br />

altruism, since it does not refer to unconditional kindness, rather being an in-kind<br />

response to beneficial or harmful acts (ibid.). Not surprisingly, such an altered<br />

conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> human action reciprocity has powerful implications for many<br />

important economic domains, while at the same time it is compatible with long term<br />

individual utility maximisation as assumed to underlie relational contracts, respectively<br />

long-term business relationships.<br />

In the conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> trust two basic types need to be held apart, according to<br />

Nooteboom, Berger, <strong>and</strong> Noorderhaven (1997): (1) competence trust, in the sense <strong>of</strong> a<br />

partner's ability to perform according to the intentions <strong>and</strong> expectations <strong>of</strong> a<br />

relationship; <strong>and</strong> (2) intentional trust, pertaining to the partner's intentions not to defect.<br />

With regard to our research framework we concentrate on intentional trust, which is<br />

path dependent <strong>and</strong> represents an idiosyncratic resource to a firm: while trust contributes<br />

to risk reduction, it cannot be instituted instantaneously, but rather needs to be<br />

established over time by developing bonds or shared norms <strong>and</strong> values. Intentional (or<br />

goodwill) trust therefore may be defined as “the expectation that an actor (1) can be<br />

relied on to fulfil obligations …, (2) will behave in a predictable manner, <strong>and</strong> (3) will<br />

act <strong>and</strong> negotiate fairly when the possibility for opportunism is present” (A. Zaheer,<br />

McEvily, & Perrone, 1998: 143).<br />

In order to further reduce the ambiguity <strong>of</strong> the conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> trust, interpersonal<br />

<strong>and</strong> inter-organisational trust need to be distinguished, which are “related but distinct<br />

constructs, <strong>and</strong> play different roles in affecting negotiation processes <strong>and</strong> exchange<br />

performance” (ibid.: 141). Inter-organisational trust is considered to be established<br />

indirectly through boundary-spanners, i.e. individuals representing each party. <strong>The</strong> latter<br />

institutionalise their trusting relationship by means <strong>of</strong> practices <strong>and</strong> routines for dealing<br />

with a partner organisation, thus creating a stable context within which interorganisational<br />

trust develops.<br />

Finally trust needs to be distinguished from trustworthiness. Trust, on one side, cannot<br />

be comm<strong>and</strong>ed <strong>and</strong> must be earned on the basis <strong>of</strong> trustworthy behaviour. It is<br />

33


34<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

situational <strong>and</strong> relationship-specific (Swift, 2001). Trustworthiness, on the other side, is<br />

a quality displayed by the parties which engenders trust <strong>and</strong> represents a link towards<br />

the construct <strong>of</strong> reputation, which is the result <strong>of</strong> consistently trustworthy behaviour<br />

(Hosmer, 1995). In accordance with Davis <strong>and</strong> Mentzer (2008: 438), we underst<strong>and</strong><br />

trustworthiness to reflect the “values, principles, <strong>and</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ards a trading partner brings<br />

to the exchange relationship; these values, principles, <strong>and</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ards are shaped over<br />

time by a firm's unique history <strong>and</strong> culture”.<br />

Within our research framework, particularly the economic relevance <strong>of</strong> trust is <strong>of</strong><br />

importance. Trust lowers the costs for specification <strong>and</strong> monitoring <strong>of</strong> contracts,<br />

provides incentives for cooperation, <strong>and</strong> reduces uncertainty (Hill, 1990). While in a<br />

low trust relation the parties are likely to engage in lengthy <strong>and</strong> difficult negotiations<br />

over unforeseen contingencies <strong>and</strong> to protect their relationship-specific investments by<br />

means <strong>of</strong> contractual safeguards in order to reduce the possibility <strong>of</strong> both ex ante <strong>and</strong> ex<br />

post opportunism (OE Williamson, 1975, 1985b), high trust conditions entail more<br />

efficient exchange governance: firms are able to lower transaction costs because<br />

agreements are reached more quickly <strong>and</strong> with fewer formal safeguards. As high asset<br />

specificity <strong>and</strong> uncertainty influence the governance structure <strong>and</strong> formal contracts <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

play a relatively limited role in such structures <strong>and</strong> relationships, other forms <strong>of</strong><br />

governance gain in significance, <strong>of</strong> which trust, reciprocity <strong>and</strong> reputation - briefly<br />

outlined in the subsequent section - are important elements.<br />

Reputation. <strong>The</strong>oretical contributions with regard to reputation research come from the<br />

disciplines <strong>of</strong> sociology, organisation theory, management strategy, marketing, <strong>and</strong><br />

economics. Although the concept has some overlaps with organisational legitimacy, the<br />

two can be delineated: while legitimacy is primarily concerned with meeting <strong>and</strong><br />

adhering to the expectations <strong>of</strong> a social system’s norms, values, rules <strong>and</strong> meanings,<br />

reputation is more related to relative st<strong>and</strong>ing, quality, esteem, favourableness, prestige,<br />

<strong>and</strong> goodwill (Deephouse & Carter, 2005), closely linked with an organisation’s<br />

“personality” (Eberl & Schwaiger, 2005). More precisely, within our research<br />

framework we consider reputation to positively affect organisational legitimacy.<br />

Through its inherent signalling function, reputation informs the public about various<br />

attributes <strong>of</strong> the firm compared to its competitors. Since different publics attend to<br />

different features <strong>of</strong> the firm's conduct, reputations reflect its relative success (Fombrun<br />

& Shanley, 1990). With the objective to align rivalling conceptualisations <strong>of</strong> (corporate)<br />

reputation, Gotsi <strong>and</strong> Wilson (2001: 25) defined it as


<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

a stakeholder’s overall evaluation <strong>of</strong> a company over time. This evaluation is based<br />

on the stakeholder’s direct experiences with the company, any other form <strong>of</strong><br />

communication <strong>and</strong> symbolism that provides information about the firm’s actions<br />

<strong>and</strong>/or a comparison with the actions <strong>of</strong> other leading rivals.<br />

Similar to trust <strong>and</strong> legitimacy, reputation may be interpreted as one <strong>of</strong> a firm’s<br />

intangible resources - in line with the RBV (Barney, 1991; Hall, 1993). It is based on<br />

the interactions <strong>of</strong> stakeholders with the firm <strong>and</strong> its representatives, <strong>and</strong> is pathdependent<br />

<strong>and</strong> idiosyncratic to the firm - thus a potential source for competitive<br />

advantage <strong>and</strong> sustainable rents. Thus viewed from an instrumental perspective,<br />

reputation as a strategic asset produces “tangible benefits: premium prices for products,<br />

lower costs for capital <strong>and</strong> labour, improved loyalty from employees, greater latitude in<br />

decision making, <strong>and</strong> a cushion <strong>of</strong> goodwill when crises hit” (Fombrun, 1996: 57).<br />

Consequently, reputation-building constitutes an investment, also as its signalling<br />

function helps stakeholders to reduce risks in their interactions with the firm, which<br />

allows the firm <strong>and</strong> its stakeholders to lower their contracting <strong>and</strong> monitoring costs<br />

(Eberl & Schwaiger, 2005).<br />

Conceptualisations <strong>of</strong> reputation are <strong>of</strong> relevance within our research framework with<br />

regard to the firm's embedding capabilities. <strong>The</strong> high visibility <strong>of</strong> UCFs <strong>and</strong> their<br />

strategic importance for national economies, give importance to the management <strong>of</strong><br />

their corporate reputation which may have considerable impact on the firm's activities<br />

<strong>and</strong> future prospects. <strong>The</strong>refore, as will be detailed later, we stipulate that a good<br />

reputation management contributes to the firm's successful embedding in its local<br />

environment.<br />

2.5 Relevant concepts <strong>of</strong> value creation<br />

Subject to the respective research tradition, value creation has been analysed from an<br />

array <strong>of</strong> perspectives, leading to widely differing approaches <strong>and</strong> underst<strong>and</strong>ings <strong>of</strong> the<br />

term. <strong>The</strong> following overview will focus on value creation in the tradition <strong>of</strong> strategic<br />

management research, excluding aspects <strong>of</strong> agency theory or the financially motivated<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing as <strong>of</strong>ten used in the leveraged buyout literature. Value creation thus is<br />

understood as being linked to a genuine change in the financial <strong>and</strong> operating<br />

performance <strong>of</strong> a firm, as opposed to value increases from a purely financial markets<br />

perspective, which is regarded as only 'value capturing' (A. Berg & Gottschalg, 2005a).<br />

35


36<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

2.5.1 Value creation within the RBV<br />

<strong>The</strong> purpose <strong>of</strong> a firm in the underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> strategic management research, <strong>and</strong> in<br />

particular the RBV, is to create sustainable competitive advantage, which is closely<br />

related to rent generation <strong>and</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it. However, there is no unity within the RBV with<br />

regard to the terminology <strong>and</strong> definitions <strong>of</strong> the latter, <strong>of</strong>ten described by “a range <strong>of</strong><br />

phrases such as 'above normal return', 'high quasi-rents', 'value creation' <strong>and</strong> other nearsynonyms<br />

for 'making money'” (Winter, 1995: 168). With the following review <strong>of</strong><br />

existing literature we try to disentangle these terms in relation to our research<br />

framework. Of particular importance in this respect are the definitions <strong>and</strong> terminology<br />

<strong>of</strong> Peteraf <strong>and</strong> Barney (2003: 314f.):<br />

Competitive Advantage<br />

An enterprise has a Competitive Advantage [italics in original] if it is able to create<br />

more economic value than the marginal (breakeven) competitor in its product<br />

market. (2003: 314f.);<br />

Economic Value<br />

<strong>The</strong> Economic Value [italics in original] created by an enterprise in the course <strong>of</strong><br />

providing a good or service is the difference between the perceived benefits gained<br />

by the purchasers <strong>of</strong> the good <strong>and</strong> the economic cost to the enterprise. 12 (2003:<br />

314f.);<br />

Economic Rent<br />

[R]eturns to a factor in excess <strong>of</strong> its opportunity costs. (2003: 314f.)<br />

In a later publication <strong>of</strong> Barney <strong>and</strong> Clark (2007), the following refining comments are<br />

made on the above definition <strong>of</strong> economic rents: it is a (1) net benefits approach to<br />

value creation, displaying the benefits from the firm's activities net <strong>of</strong> their costs; it is<br />

(2) closely aligned with fundamental economic principles, basically reflecting the<br />

concept <strong>of</strong> total surplus; furthermore it emphasises (3) perceived benefits, rather than<br />

absolute notions <strong>of</strong> quality differentials - consistent with the marketing view <strong>of</strong> value<br />

creation; <strong>and</strong> lastly it supports an (4) efficiency view <strong>of</strong> the RBV, stipulating that greater<br />

value means greater efficiency. Special consideration is thereby given to critical<br />

resources, i.e. factors with a high contribution to value creation. What the above<br />

definition leaves out is the issue <strong>of</strong> value appropriation, i.e. who ultimately receives the<br />

12 For the sake <strong>of</strong> clarity, economic value shall be delineated from the 'value added' term used in<br />

accounting, referring to the additional value <strong>of</strong> a commodity over the cost <strong>of</strong> commodities used to<br />

produce it from the previous stage <strong>of</strong> production.


<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

generated rent, as well as the question <strong>of</strong> the rent's sustainability. <strong>The</strong>refore it is<br />

important to note that rent generation ability <strong>and</strong> superior pr<strong>of</strong>itability are not<br />

necessarily linked.<br />

Conditions for value creation. According to the RBV differences in firm performance<br />

may be explained by differences in (the efficiency <strong>of</strong>) resource-usage. Firms create<br />

economic value not due to mere possession <strong>of</strong> resources but due to the effective <strong>and</strong><br />

innovative management <strong>of</strong> resources (Penrose, 1959), i.e. the unique interplay between<br />

physical capital resources, financial capital resources, human capital resources, <strong>and</strong><br />

organisational capital resources over time (cf. Barney & Clark, 2007). <strong>The</strong> theoretical<br />

conditions which underpin competitive advantage <strong>and</strong> rent generation, <strong>and</strong> all <strong>of</strong> which<br />

have to be met, are defined as follows (Peteraf, 1993):<br />

- resource heterogeneity 13 , creating Ricardian or monopoly rents<br />

- ex-post limits to competition, preventing the rents to be competed away<br />

- imperfect resource mobility, ensuring that valuable factors remain in the firm<br />

- ex-ante limits to competition, keeping the costs from <strong>of</strong>fsetting the rents<br />

Complementary to this view, the dynamic capabilities perspective focuses on the value<br />

drivers related to the creation, evolution <strong>and</strong> the recombination <strong>of</strong> these resources which<br />

lead to new sources <strong>of</strong> competitive advantage (Melé & Guillén, 2006).<br />

<strong>The</strong>se conditions for value creation are interesting with regard to our research subject,<br />

respectively with regard to the industries to which UCFs belong, in particular due to the<br />

latter's high regulatory density <strong>and</strong> the requirement <strong>of</strong> a state concession for operation,<br />

combined with significant sunk cost <strong>and</strong> heavy infrastructure.<br />

2.5.2 Value creation through synergy realisation<br />

From the perspective <strong>of</strong> strategic management the logic behind firms' motivation to<br />

exp<strong>and</strong> is rooted in the better exploitation <strong>of</strong> the firm's existing resources. Thus, firms<br />

are able to create synergies, defined as “the value that is created <strong>and</strong> captured, over time,<br />

by the sum <strong>of</strong> the businesses together relative to what it would be separately” (J. Martin<br />

& Eisenhardt, 2001: 3). Importantly, synergies may spring from cost reductions, as well<br />

as revenue enhancements <strong>and</strong> they are <strong>of</strong> use to the firm only as long as the resulting<br />

rent is also captured by it. An aspect which is frequently underestimated by firms:<br />

synergy exploitation does not come for free <strong>and</strong> has realisation costs to it, consisting <strong>of</strong><br />

13 Resource heterogeneity is understood in the sense that some firms have resources that generate more<br />

value than others.<br />

37


38<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

direct costs <strong>of</strong> coordination <strong>and</strong> controlling, <strong>and</strong> indirect costs <strong>of</strong> compromise <strong>and</strong><br />

inflexibility (A. Campbell & Goold, 2000).<br />

Pertaining to the types <strong>of</strong> synergies that firms may create, Knoll (2008: 25) has<br />

established a comprehensive classification with regard to multi-business firms,<br />

essentially dividing them in four major groups: (1) operative synergies, defined as<br />

performance advantages <strong>of</strong> multi-business firms from leveraging operative resources<br />

across their related businesses; (2) market power synergies, as the performance<br />

advantages <strong>of</strong> multi-business firms from leveraging market power resources across their<br />

businesses; (3) financial synergies, as the performance advantages <strong>of</strong> multi-business<br />

firms from leveraging financial resources across their businesses; <strong>and</strong> (4) corporate<br />

management synergies, which are defined as performance advantages <strong>of</strong> multi-business<br />

firms from leveraging corporate management resources across their businesses. We<br />

have integrated this synergy typology in our framework, throughout the description <strong>of</strong><br />

which we will come back to the concept <strong>of</strong> synergy in more detail.<br />

<strong>The</strong> notion <strong>of</strong> synergy creation is <strong>of</strong> particular importance in the second part <strong>of</strong> our<br />

research framework which is concerned with value creation among multiple sites <strong>of</strong> the<br />

firm. Accordingly we will further elaborate our underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> value creation in<br />

chapter four - in the first part with regard to the single site firm, <strong>and</strong> in the second part<br />

with regard to these multiple units, under particular consideration <strong>of</strong> synergies.<br />

2.6 Conclusion<br />

Based on our research strategy, following grounded theory methodology <strong>and</strong> employing<br />

a multi-lens approach to our research questions, the review <strong>of</strong> literature played a<br />

dominant role throughout our research process. On the basis <strong>of</strong> an open-minded<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> grounded theory we have immersed in the various fields <strong>of</strong> literature<br />

already in the planning <strong>of</strong> our empirical phase. <strong>The</strong> introduction to the relevant<br />

theoretical lenses <strong>and</strong> concepts for our research framework is deliberately kept brief in<br />

order avoid redundancies, as we will return to these concepts <strong>and</strong> related literature in<br />

more detail throughout chapter four. <strong>The</strong> objective <strong>of</strong> this chapter therefore is to provide<br />

the reader with an overview <strong>and</strong> underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the key terms <strong>of</strong> existing research as<br />

understood in our research, such as to facilitate the further reading.<br />

Two major fields <strong>of</strong> research have been defining for the development <strong>of</strong> our research<br />

framework: strategic management research - as a part <strong>of</strong> organisation theory - <strong>and</strong> (new)<br />

institutionalism, whose core concepts are closely interlinked with the fields <strong>of</strong> economic


<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

geography <strong>and</strong> economic sociology. Due to these conceptual overlaps a clear attribution<br />

<strong>of</strong> the defining notions - while we have attempted it - was not always possible. In<br />

particular the notion <strong>of</strong> embeddedness <strong>and</strong> a number <strong>of</strong> concepts originating from TCE<br />

have constituted links between the individual research lenses, in some cases facilitating<br />

their logically consistent weaving into an overall multi-lens framework, in others<br />

making a clear delineation <strong>and</strong> decision for one perspective necessary. Table 2-1<br />

provides an overview on the defining elements <strong>of</strong> the employed research lenses <strong>and</strong><br />

their relevance in addressing our research questions.<br />

39


40<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical Embedding <strong>and</strong> Literature Review<br />

Table 2-3: Summary <strong>of</strong> key elements from the relevant theoretical research lenses


Empirical Approach<br />

3 Empirical Approach<br />

In the literature review in chapter two we reviewed existing theory pertaining to our<br />

research topic <strong>and</strong> research questions. In chapter three we expound our research<br />

perspective, as well as the empirical approach towards deriving the answers to our<br />

research questions. In its traditional conception, the essence <strong>of</strong> science as a method<br />

may be divided into data <strong>and</strong> theory. In hierarchical terms, science accepts authority <strong>of</strong><br />

data over theory: while theory explains the world, its ideas have to be tested against<br />

empirical data in order to validate them. However, chronologically it is irrelevant<br />

which comes first - theory or data, as long as both are present (Punch, 2005). Bearing<br />

these fundamentals in mind, we will start by outlining the research paradigm<br />

underlying our research.<br />

3.1 Research paradigm <strong>and</strong> research perspective<br />

Paradigms encompass a number <strong>of</strong> characteristic theories <strong>and</strong> models that explain <strong>and</strong><br />

relate the variables defining subject matter (Mohrman & Lawler, 1985). <strong>The</strong>y<br />

represent a “worldview that defines, for its holder, the nature <strong>of</strong> the 'world', the<br />

individual's place in it, <strong>and</strong> the range <strong>of</strong> possible relationships to that world <strong>and</strong> its<br />

parts” (Guba & Lincoln, 1994: 105). From a scientific point <strong>of</strong> view, paradigms denote<br />

a universally accepted set <strong>of</strong> models shared by the members <strong>of</strong> a specific scientific<br />

community (Kuhn, 1962). <strong>The</strong>y shall help readers to evaluate the findings, by being<br />

able to comprehend the terms <strong>and</strong> process <strong>of</strong> research. Revealing the underlying<br />

scientific assumptions is crucial in order to follow the researcher's conceptual<br />

argumentation <strong>and</strong> to underst<strong>and</strong> the subsequent results. In accordance with Guba <strong>and</strong><br />

Lincoln (1994), these underlying assumptions, respectively paradigms can be made<br />

transparent by answering three principal questions:<br />

- Ontological position: how is the form <strong>and</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> reality perceived?<br />

- Epistemological position: what is the nature <strong>of</strong> the relationship between the<br />

inquirer <strong>and</strong> the known?<br />

- Methodological position: which process is chosen by the inquirer in order to<br />

find answers to the research questions? Finding answers to this last question<br />

goes beyond the pure choice <strong>of</strong> methods, which have to be aligned to a<br />

predetermined methodology<br />

41


42<br />

Empirical Approach<br />

On the continuum <strong>of</strong> the ontological assumptions between the fundamental positions<br />

<strong>of</strong> realism <strong>and</strong> idealism, science distinguishes between three principal paradigms. On<br />

the realism-end <strong>of</strong> the continuum, there is the (1) positivistic paradigm, which assumes<br />

reality as objectively given, existing independent <strong>of</strong> the observer. Its scientific aim is<br />

to approximate <strong>and</strong> describe the world as correctly as possible. Furthermore, (2) postpositivism<br />

equally bases assumptions on an objective reality. However, this reality can<br />

only be apprehended imperfectly, because <strong>of</strong> flawed human intellectual mechanisms.<br />

Scientifically, findings are acknowledged as being true until they have empirically<br />

been proven false (Popper, 1976). Last but not least, science distinguishes (3)<br />

constructivism, whose social realities are the product <strong>of</strong> human intellects <strong>and</strong> are<br />

potentially conflicting. <strong>The</strong> content <strong>of</strong> human consciousness is assumed to be as<br />

accessible as reality; constructivists apprehend the world by means <strong>of</strong> social<br />

constructs, such as language, consciousness, or shared meanings.<br />

In order to approach the formulated research questions, we have adopted postpositivism's<br />

notion <strong>of</strong> a socially constructed reality. Under this perspective the task <strong>of</strong><br />

the social scientist is not defined by fact-gathering <strong>and</strong> pattern-measuring, but rather<br />

by appreciating the different constructions <strong>and</strong> meanings that people place upon their<br />

experience. This paradigm appears most appropriate for the topic <strong>and</strong> type <strong>of</strong> research<br />

questions, <strong>and</strong> the consequently chosen qualitative approach <strong>of</strong> this dissertation.<br />

Congruously, the post-positivist position allows for the combination <strong>of</strong> multiple data<br />

collection <strong>and</strong> analysis methods, as well as the inclusion <strong>of</strong> various kinds <strong>of</strong> data<br />

(Stablein, 1996: 537), with the purpose <strong>of</strong> capturing the different facets <strong>of</strong> an<br />

underlying yet unknown reality (Denzin & Lincoln, 2000). To sum up, we underst<strong>and</strong><br />

scientific research as a learning process, wherein our constructs are shaped<br />

accompanied by theoretical intent <strong>and</strong> based on systematic knowledge through<br />

experience (see also Kubicek, 1977).<br />

3.2 Research methodology<br />

In the history <strong>of</strong> science there is a long <strong>and</strong> enduring debate on the value <strong>of</strong> qualitative<br />

versus quantitative research. Based on the positivistic end <strong>of</strong> the ontological<br />

continuum, quantitative research seeks the causal determination <strong>and</strong> generalisation <strong>of</strong><br />

findings. In contrast, qualitative research is oriented towards the constructivist end <strong>of</strong><br />

the scale, seeking illumination, underst<strong>and</strong>ing, <strong>and</strong> extrapolation to similar situations.<br />

From the perspective <strong>of</strong> the social sciences neither approach is superior to the other,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the choice <strong>of</strong> method <strong>and</strong> use <strong>of</strong> data need to be based on the questions being


Empirical Approach<br />

asked. In other words, there is agreement to attribute “logical priority <strong>of</strong> questions over<br />

methods” (Punch, 2000: 6).<br />

Based on our research subject <strong>and</strong> the associated research questions, as outlined in<br />

chapter one, the purpose <strong>of</strong> our research is to better underst<strong>and</strong> the construct <strong>of</strong><br />

location-fixity <strong>and</strong> how it affects the firm's value creation opportunities. Since the<br />

characteristics <strong>and</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity are not yet scientifically illuminated, our<br />

aim is to contribute to the advancement <strong>and</strong> building <strong>of</strong> theory, mainly in the fields <strong>of</strong><br />

strategic management <strong>and</strong> institutional economics. Consequently, we have chosen an<br />

inductive research strategy, focusing on qualitative research methodologies. This<br />

qualitative orientation is supported by our rather contextual 14 research topic <strong>and</strong> the<br />

employed multi-lens perspective, including research areas such as strategic<br />

management, institutional economics, economic geography, <strong>and</strong> economic sociology.<br />

On the basis <strong>of</strong> these considerations we have adopted an inductive case study<br />

approach, guided by the principles <strong>of</strong> grounded theory.<br />

3.2.1 Inductive research<br />

Qualitative research refers to “any kind <strong>of</strong> research that produces findings, not arrived<br />

at by means <strong>of</strong> statistical procedures or other means <strong>of</strong> quantification” (Strauss &<br />

Corbin, 1990: 17). It is inherently inductive, “leading from the particular to the<br />

general, the individual to the whole, the concrete to the abstract” (Bortz & Döring,<br />

2006: 300). Being multidimensional <strong>and</strong> pluralistic with respect to paradigms, its<br />

purpose is to explore the reality by capturing <strong>and</strong> interpreting real-world <strong>and</strong> authentic<br />

experience. Inductive methods allow to apprehend <strong>and</strong> underst<strong>and</strong> the research topic in<br />

its width <strong>and</strong> depth (Kromrey, 2006). Consequently, inductive methods may be used to<br />

better underst<strong>and</strong> any phenomenon about which little is yet known, gain new<br />

perspectives on things about which much is already known, <strong>and</strong> to gain more in-depth<br />

information that may be difficult to convey quantitatively (Strauss & Corbin, 1990). In<br />

his 'Introduction to Social Research', Punch (2005) classifies the major inductive<br />

strategies for qualitative research methods into case research; ethnography <strong>and</strong><br />

grounded theory, as well as language-based strategies. <strong>The</strong>se research strategies may<br />

14 Yeung (2000: 13) clearly recommends a qualitative orientation for contextual research topics:<br />

"Since quantitative data are not sensitive to variations in experiences at the individual social actor<br />

level, they are not valid measurement <strong>of</strong> the rationale <strong>and</strong> behaviour <strong>of</strong> these social actors. If we take<br />

the economic action <strong>of</strong> these actors as socially embedded, the validity <strong>of</strong> quantitative data is even<br />

more questionable because indicators <strong>of</strong> economic action may not be compatible with measuring<br />

social <strong>and</strong> cultural behaviour".<br />

43


44<br />

Empirical Approach<br />

be exploratory, descriptive, or explanatory in nature, depending on conditions such as<br />

the type <strong>of</strong> the research question(s), the extent <strong>of</strong> control <strong>of</strong> the researcher over actual<br />

behavioural events, <strong>and</strong> how much the researcher focuses on contemporary versus<br />

historical events (Yin, 1994).<br />

In the following subsections, we briefly introduce the approaches <strong>of</strong> grounded theory<br />

<strong>and</strong> case study research, <strong>and</strong> further outline the reasoning for choosing those two<br />

approaches.<br />

3.2.2 Grounded theory<br />

<strong>The</strong> methodology <strong>of</strong> grounded theory represents the extreme approach on the inductive<br />

methodological spectre (Göthlich, 2003). It guides theory generation by collecting <strong>and</strong><br />

analysing data in an iterative process (Denzin & Lincoln, 2000; Glaser & Strauss,<br />

1967). In the early phases <strong>of</strong> grounded theorising, the researcher goes through a<br />

creative stage, allowing her maximum flexibility in generating new categories from<br />

data, thus mitigating the inhibition <strong>of</strong> the research process by overly rigid<br />

methodological prescriptions (Pidgeon, 2002). Importantly, grounded theory is shaped<br />

by two fundamental analytical commitments, which clearly separate it from traditional<br />

content analysis or other forms <strong>of</strong> thematic analysis: it insists on constant comparison<br />

<strong>and</strong> on the use <strong>of</strong> theoretical sampling. Constant comparison requires the continual<br />

sifting <strong>and</strong> comparing <strong>of</strong> elements throughout the lifetime <strong>of</strong> the research in order to<br />

grasp the complexity, the similarities <strong>and</strong> differences <strong>of</strong> the researched field, thus<br />

enhancing concept <strong>and</strong> theory development. <strong>The</strong> second commitment, theoretical<br />

sampling, requires that characteristics <strong>and</strong> sample size are not predetermined. Rather,<br />

they are influenced by the developing theory, which guides the researcher towards new<br />

informants <strong>and</strong> appropriate locations (Goulding, 1998). Sampling therefore is mainly<br />

driven by theoretical concerns, <strong>and</strong> cases should extend or deepen the researcher's<br />

emergent underst<strong>and</strong>ing. Although this method supports the building <strong>of</strong> theory, the<br />

researcher must be aware “that enquiry is always context bound <strong>and</strong> facts should be<br />

viewed as both theory laden <strong>and</strong> value laden” (Goulding, 1998: 53). As an inductive<br />

research methodology, grounded theory requires some theoretical sensitivity (Glaser &<br />

Strauss, 1967) <strong>of</strong> the researcher, with regard to determining the point where research<br />

reaches saturation: “<strong>The</strong> signals <strong>of</strong> saturation, which include repetition <strong>of</strong> information<br />

<strong>and</strong> confirmation <strong>of</strong> existing conceptual categories, are inherently pragmatic <strong>and</strong><br />

depend upon both the empirical context <strong>and</strong> the researcher’s experience <strong>and</strong> expertise”<br />

(Suddaby, 2006: 639). Consequently, grounded theory is foremost an interpretive<br />

process <strong>and</strong> not a logico-deductive one.


Empirical Approach<br />

Open-minded grounded theory. <strong>The</strong>re are various streams within grounded theory,<br />

reaching from the radical theorising method by Glaser (1992), which requires<br />

researchers to start empirical research with no up-front theory assumptions, to the<br />

more moderate approaches which acknowledge the need for a priori immersion in<br />

existing theory. <strong>The</strong> recent literature on empirical social research promotes a<br />

knowledge-based approach in qualitative studies, as suggested by Strauss <strong>and</strong> Corbin<br />

(1990). Knowledge-generation <strong>and</strong> theory-building thereby are fostered through a<br />

constant interplay <strong>of</strong> inductive <strong>and</strong> deductive steps. Within our research project, we<br />

follow this more recent version <strong>of</strong> grounded theory, which Frank <strong>and</strong> Riedl (2004) also<br />

refer to as the 'open-minded' approach. Through familiarisation with existing literature,<br />

the researcher is sensitised towards new issues (Yin, 1994), which thus facilitates the<br />

transfer <strong>of</strong> existing ideas to new theory by the interplay <strong>of</strong> holistic theoretical analysis<br />

<strong>and</strong> the evaluation <strong>of</strong> collected evidence.<br />

Reasons for choosing grounded theory methodology. With regard to our<br />

dissertation, open-minded grounded theory <strong>of</strong>fers a number <strong>of</strong> distinct advantages,<br />

such as its (1) explorative character - since we approach our dissertation project from<br />

a multi-lens perspective, the structured approach provided by grounded theory<br />

methodology supports the generation <strong>of</strong> new insights by linking gained evidence with<br />

consistent theory 15 ; its (2) theory building character - due to the absence <strong>of</strong> existing<br />

theory with regard to the characteristics <strong>and</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> our location-fixity construct,<br />

grounded theory facilitates the grounding <strong>and</strong> further specification <strong>of</strong> location-fixity,<br />

thus contributing to theory generation; <strong>and</strong> lastly its (3) interpretive <strong>and</strong> inductive<br />

character - grounded theory eases the comprehension <strong>of</strong> complex theoretical<br />

assertions <strong>and</strong> increases their validity, because they directly derive from empirical data<br />

(Strauss & Corbin, 1990). In our empirical phase these advantages became particularly<br />

evident throughout the process <strong>of</strong> continuous comparison, which has contributed to the<br />

gradual identification <strong>of</strong> our research framework's elements, <strong>and</strong> to an underst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

how they are related to each other.<br />

3.3 Case research<br />

Case research may be considered as one <strong>of</strong> the most effective methods in the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> new theory. It may employ qualitative as well as quantitative methods<br />

(Göthlich, 2003), consequently being allocated in between the inductive <strong>and</strong> the<br />

15<br />

According to Meinefeld (2004) only the explicit linking <strong>of</strong> newly generated insights with existing<br />

theoretical knowledge constitutes genuine expansion <strong>of</strong> knowledge.<br />

45


46<br />

Empirical Approach<br />

deductive spectre. <strong>The</strong> case study, being the unit <strong>of</strong> analysis in case research, may be<br />

defined as an empirical inquiry that “investigates a contemporary phenomenon within<br />

its real-life context, especially when the boundaries between phenomenon <strong>and</strong> context<br />

are not clearly evident” (Yin, 1994: 13). Thus, case studies are particularly useful in<br />

forming a basis from which to develop theory inductively, whereby the emergent<br />

theory is developed by “recognising patterns <strong>of</strong> relationship among constructs within<br />

<strong>and</strong> across cases <strong>and</strong> their underlying logical arguments [emphasis in original]”<br />

(Eisenhardt & Graebner, 2007: 25). Consequently, they <strong>of</strong>fer the opportunity for<br />

holistically viewing a process, as opposed to the <strong>of</strong>ten employed reductionistfragmented<br />

view. Importantly, case studies differ from other research strategies, such<br />

as experiments or action research, in the researcher's inability to manipulate the<br />

research object. Consequently, they are optimally suited as an approach for such<br />

situations <strong>of</strong> little or no control (Reason & Rowan, 1981).<br />

Case study designs. Depending on the purpose <strong>of</strong> the research, different case-study<br />

designs may be applied. Yin (1994) identifies four basic case study types,<br />

distinguishing between single- <strong>and</strong> multiple-case designs, respectively holistic versus<br />

embedded cases, as illustrated in Figure 3-1 below.<br />

holistic<br />

(single unit <strong>of</strong> analysis)<br />

embedded<br />

(multiple units <strong>of</strong> analysis)<br />

Figure 3-1: Basic types <strong>of</strong> case study designs 16<br />

single-case designs multiple-case designs<br />

Type 1 Type 3<br />

Type 2 Type 4<br />

Single-case designs are chosen for arguments similar to the reasons for single<br />

experiments. <strong>The</strong>y may serve for the testing <strong>of</strong> a well-formulated theory by means <strong>of</strong> a<br />

16 Yin, 1994.


Empirical Approach<br />

critical case, as representation <strong>of</strong> an extreme or unique case, or they may be revelatory<br />

in nature. In research designs with multiple stages, a single case might help as a pilot<br />

case for the exploration <strong>of</strong> a research theme. Importantly, single case studies require<br />

very careful scrutiny <strong>of</strong> the potential case, since all eggs are being put into one basket.<br />

In contrast, multiple-case study designs require the researcher to pay attention to the<br />

issues <strong>of</strong> research resources <strong>and</strong> the motives for case selection. Yin (1994: 45)<br />

stipulates that “every case should serve a specific purpose within the overall scope <strong>of</strong><br />

inquiry”. Compared to the single case, multiple-case study designs usually produce<br />

more compelling evidence, resulting in higher robustness <strong>of</strong> the overall results. As for<br />

the holistic or embedded case study design, the unit <strong>of</strong> analysis is decisive. While<br />

holistic case studies only focus on one unit <strong>of</strong> analysis, embedded designs involve a<br />

main unit <strong>of</strong> analysis, but include also a sub-unit or sub-units to be researched (Yin,<br />

1994).<br />

Reasons for choosing the case research approach. With regard to our research topic<br />

<strong>and</strong> research questions, a case study approach <strong>of</strong>fers the opportunity to holistically<br />

investigate the context-sensitive constructs <strong>of</strong> location-fixity, local exposure, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

notion <strong>of</strong> local embedding. By being able to obtain context-rich information from<br />

different data sources <strong>and</strong> several cases, the shaping <strong>and</strong> refining <strong>of</strong> our research<br />

framework was greatly facilitated. To this effect we have employed an embedded<br />

multiple case design. As to increase the external validity <strong>of</strong> our findings, we have<br />

selected three case study objects from different industries by means <strong>of</strong> purposeful<br />

sampling (Patton, 1990). Moreover, multiple case studies typically provide a stronger<br />

base for theory building (Yin, 1994). <strong>The</strong> sampling process <strong>and</strong> criteria will be further<br />

detailed in the subsequent section 3.4, as part <strong>of</strong> an overall description <strong>of</strong> our research<br />

design.<br />

3.4 Research design<br />

<strong>The</strong> research design describes the logical sequence which links our empirical findings<br />

with the research questions (cf. Yin, 1994). Generally, research design is defined as<br />

“the overall configuration <strong>of</strong> a piece <strong>of</strong> research: what kind <strong>of</strong> evidence is gathered,<br />

from where, <strong>and</strong> how such evidence is interpreted in order to provide good answers to<br />

the basic research question(s)” (Easterby-Smith, Thorpe, & Lowe, 1991: 21). As<br />

outlined before, we have chosen for our dissertation an inductive research strategy that<br />

includes an embedded multiple-case design <strong>and</strong> employs grounded theory<br />

methodology. This methodological choice is further supported on the basis <strong>of</strong> Yin's<br />

47


48<br />

Empirical Approach<br />

(1994) criteria for identification <strong>of</strong> the appropriate research strategy: (1) the type <strong>of</strong><br />

research question, (2) the extent <strong>of</strong> control <strong>of</strong> the researcher over actual behavioural<br />

events, <strong>and</strong> (3) the degree to which the research focuses on contemporary events.<br />

Pertaining to the first criterion, our research questions are <strong>of</strong> exploratory <strong>and</strong><br />

explanatory character, as detailed in Table 3-1.<br />

Research question Categorisation<br />

1. What are the defining elements <strong>of</strong> location-fixity? exploratory<br />

2. How do location-fixity <strong>and</strong> the related institutional exposure<br />

affect our research object?<br />

3. How does the resulting local exposure affect the value<br />

creation <strong>of</strong> our research object?<br />

4. How can firms mitigate the effects <strong>of</strong> local exposure? explanatory<br />

5. How does location-fixity impact our research object's multiunit<br />

resource management?<br />

6. How can the multi-site UCF create value under the condition<br />

<strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> local exposure?<br />

7. What are the theoretical <strong>and</strong> practical implications for<br />

companies pertaining to our research object?<br />

Table 3-1: Categorisation <strong>of</strong> research questions 17<br />

exploratory, explanatory<br />

exploratory, explanatory<br />

explanatory<br />

exploratory, explanatory<br />

exploratory<br />

On the second <strong>and</strong> third criteria, the research subject clearly focuses on contemporary<br />

events, whereby the relevant aspects under investigation may not be controlled or<br />

manipulated. All <strong>of</strong> these circumstances suggest case research as the optimal research<br />

strategy.<br />

3.4.1 Conceptual framework<br />

<strong>The</strong> conceptual framework <strong>of</strong> a research project describes the “conceptual status <strong>of</strong> the<br />

things being studied, <strong>and</strong> their relationship to each other” (Punch, 2000: 54). In<br />

accordance with the explorative character <strong>of</strong> our research, we started with a simplified<br />

framework which evolved throughout our research process until reaching the point <strong>of</strong><br />

saturation, where no more substantially different information could be gathered. As a<br />

result, the initial simplified research framework underwent numerous variations along<br />

17 On the basis <strong>of</strong> Yin (1994).


Empirical Approach<br />

the generation <strong>of</strong> new insights. Figure 3-2 illustrates the simplified research framework<br />

which emerged from the process <strong>of</strong> refinement, <strong>and</strong> how the research questions (RQ)<br />

relate to parts <strong>of</strong> the framework, respectively its constructs.<br />

RQ 1, RQ 2<br />

embedding<br />

capabilities<br />

local exposure from<br />

location fixity<br />

RQ 4 moderate<br />

RQ 3<br />

value creation<br />

influences<br />

Figure 3-2: Simplified research framework <strong>and</strong> reference to research questions<br />

We initially started our research by supposing a link between the core constructs <strong>of</strong><br />

location-fixity, plus the related local exposure, <strong>and</strong> the firm's opportunities for value<br />

creation, moderated by yet to be identified managerial capabilities within the firm. In<br />

accordance with our theory-building approach, the objective <strong>of</strong> our empirical process<br />

was to not only verify these links with regard to our case study objects, but to generate<br />

insights on the specifics <strong>and</strong> characteristics <strong>of</strong> those constructs.<br />

In a second part <strong>of</strong> our conceptual framework, we focused on the multiple unit firm<br />

<strong>and</strong> value creation opportunities in the interaction between its location-fixed sites.<br />

<strong>The</strong>reby the role <strong>of</strong> the corporate parent, with its stock <strong>of</strong> experience from the various<br />

units, is <strong>of</strong> particular interest. Based on the insights from the single unit environment<br />

<strong>of</strong> location-fixed firms, the objective was to gain insights on how the corporate parent<br />

may support its locally embedded units in value-creating ways.<br />

3.4.2 Research object<br />

Before we further describe our data sources <strong>and</strong> the criteria <strong>of</strong> case selection, in this<br />

section we elaborate the characteristics <strong>of</strong> our research object. <strong>The</strong> initial impulses for<br />

the research topic originated from the airport sector - a significantly location-fixed,<br />

infrastructure-heavy <strong>and</strong> highly regulated industry. However, under the aspect <strong>of</strong><br />

external validity we widened the research focus to include those industries that share<br />

the same central characteristics, in order to identify similarities <strong>and</strong> differences in their<br />

coping with location-fixity. During our process <strong>of</strong> constant comparison <strong>and</strong> theoretical<br />

sampling, the joint characteristics <strong>of</strong> these industries became more apparent <strong>and</strong> their<br />

contours more clear-cut. Based on these industries' dependence on large-scale physical<br />

infrastructure, which ties them to a specific location, they share three features which<br />

are <strong>of</strong> significance within the RBV <strong>and</strong> the TCE:<br />

49


50<br />

Empirical Approach<br />

- <strong>The</strong>y are dependent on a natural resource, which is available at a certain<br />

location <strong>and</strong> which is immobile or movable only at great cost.<br />

- <strong>The</strong>y have a high degree <strong>of</strong> dedicated assets, due to their discrete investments in<br />

infrastructure, which loses its value if employed in alternative uses.<br />

- <strong>The</strong>y are confronted with high entry <strong>and</strong> exit barriers, due to the nature <strong>of</strong> the<br />

industry <strong>and</strong> the type <strong>of</strong> activity, which require particular circumstances to enter<br />

the industry, but make it equally difficult to stop these activities<br />

In summary, our research object refers to three types <strong>of</strong> large-scale infrastructures, i.e.<br />

(1) transportation assets, such as airports, railways, <strong>and</strong> seaports; (2) utility networks,<br />

including gas, water, <strong>and</strong> electricity; <strong>and</strong> (3) resource extraction facilities, pertaining to<br />

mines, <strong>of</strong>fshore platforms, or pipelines. What they have in common is their strategic<br />

role within our large socio-technical systems <strong>and</strong> their high importance for the<br />

functioning <strong>of</strong> national economies, which makes them assets <strong>of</strong> national strategic<br />

interest (Gil & Beckman, 2009). Importantly, firms which operate in these industries<br />

share the following particular characteristics:<br />

High capital needs <strong>and</strong> sunk costs. <strong>The</strong> activities <strong>of</strong> our research object involve large<br />

sunk investments in order to be able to deliver essential services to the public. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

capital requirements represent a significant entry barrier to newcomers. All the while,<br />

these sunk costs tie the firm to the chosen location <strong>and</strong> makes it location-dependent<br />

<strong>and</strong> to a certain extent exposed to its local stakeholders.<br />

Long planning horizon. <strong>The</strong>se major investments in site-specific infrastructure impose<br />

a long-term orientation on the firm. Additional factors promoting a long-term<br />

perspective are the complexity <strong>of</strong> the operation, which requires highly specialised<br />

know-how; the strategic importance <strong>of</strong> the infrastructure, respectively the firm's<br />

outputs; the stepped costs <strong>of</strong> the firm's capacity planning; <strong>and</strong> the resulting long<br />

amortisation periods <strong>of</strong> the related infrastructure.<br />

Sovereign m<strong>and</strong>ates <strong>and</strong> concessions. <strong>The</strong> firms in our focus are subject to contractual<br />

obligations from state-granted licenses, property-rights, <strong>and</strong> concessions. <strong>The</strong>y have<br />

received “a grant <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong> or property especially by a government in return for services<br />

or for a particular use” (concession, 2010), respectively they have been granted “a<br />

right to undertake <strong>and</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it by a specified activity” (ibid.). As a consequence, they<br />

have not only financially committed themselves, but they have a sovereign m<strong>and</strong>ate<br />

<strong>and</strong> obligation for the fulfilment <strong>of</strong> these tasks, as contractually agreed. Such<br />

obligations may result in multiple <strong>and</strong> partly conflicting interests with regard to the<br />

firm's activities. Most prominently the firm's pr<strong>of</strong>it orientation may be in conflict with


Empirical Approach<br />

the sovereign's expectations regarding the provision <strong>of</strong> quasi-public goods, vital to the<br />

national economy.<br />

Path dependency. As a consequence <strong>of</strong> the first three characteristics, our research<br />

object's activities are highly path-dependent. <strong>The</strong> irreversibility <strong>of</strong> decisions once<br />

taken severely influences its future options <strong>and</strong> the available development paths.<br />

Quasi-monopolistic industry structure. <strong>The</strong> industries pertaining to our research object<br />

are predominantly characterised by monopolistic structures. Such structures are<br />

encouraged by the capital intensive nature <strong>of</strong> infrastructure, combined with the<br />

longevity <strong>and</strong> immobility <strong>of</strong> the assets, which collectively lead to sub-additive cost <strong>of</strong><br />

production functions 18 . Such natural monopolies are problematic with regard to the<br />

firm's long-term fulfilment <strong>of</strong> its sovereign m<strong>and</strong>ate. Consequently, the firm's<br />

stakeholders, particularly the sovereign (public) ones, are concerned to protect<br />

themselves “against the unregulated exercise <strong>of</strong> market power that a natural monopoly<br />

makes possible” (Newbery, 2003: 3).<br />

High regulatory density. As a result <strong>of</strong> the prior points, most <strong>of</strong> these firms are heavily<br />

regulated, whereby the sovereign attempts to substitute the market through a<br />

functioning regulatory system. By means <strong>of</strong> such regulation the firm's adequate<br />

fulfilment <strong>of</strong> its sovereign m<strong>and</strong>ate shall be ensured in the public interest.<br />

As an aggregate denomination <strong>of</strong> the industries, to which the above characteristics<br />

apply, we therefore refer to them as Utilities <strong>and</strong> Concession-based Industries',<br />

respectively UCI, consequently denominating our research object as Utilities <strong>and</strong><br />

Concession-based Firms, in short UCF.<br />

3.4.3 Unit <strong>of</strong> analysis<br />

Within case research the unit <strong>of</strong> analysis defines what the case study is focusing on,<br />

respectively what the case is (B. Berg, 2001). <strong>The</strong> case may be defined as a bounded<br />

system (M. Miles & Huberman, 1994; Stake, 1995), whose limitations in data<br />

collection <strong>and</strong> analysis, <strong>and</strong> in the application <strong>of</strong> the findings need to be determined on<br />

three general categories, i.e. space, time, <strong>and</strong> values (Bacharach, 1989). Importantly,<br />

different analyses in the same study may have different units <strong>of</strong> analysis.<br />

With regard to our research project, the bisection <strong>of</strong> the research model in two distinct<br />

parts results in two levels <strong>of</strong> analysis. In the first part we focus on the firm's local unit<br />

18 I.e. a decrease <strong>of</strong> overall production-cost, when production is concentrated within one firm (Aberle,<br />

2003).<br />

51


52<br />

Empirical Approach<br />

or site as the primary unit <strong>of</strong> analysis, more specifically the firm's relations <strong>and</strong><br />

interaction with its local environment in which it is embedded. In addition, the<br />

capabilities <strong>of</strong> the firm's local managers represent our sub-unit <strong>of</strong> analysis. In contrast,<br />

the second part <strong>of</strong> the framework focuses on the multiple-unit firm, which consists <strong>of</strong> a<br />

corporate parent <strong>and</strong> geographically dispersed local units which interact inter se.<br />

<strong>The</strong>reby the interaction between the corporate parent <strong>and</strong> its individual unit may be<br />

considered as primary unit <strong>of</strong> analysis. Equally, the interaction between the firm's units<br />

themselves in the sense <strong>of</strong> cross-site collaboration also finds consideration. On the<br />

dimension <strong>of</strong> space, the scope <strong>of</strong> the research model is limited to firms within utilities<br />

<strong>and</strong> concession-based industries, as detailed in sub-chapter 3.4.2. <strong>The</strong> research object<br />

is assumed to be allocated in a highly regulated institutional environment, which<br />

principally functions as a market economy under prevalence <strong>of</strong> the rule <strong>of</strong> law - which<br />

may be considered as part <strong>of</strong> the values, respectively the context within which the<br />

cases are allocated. In respect <strong>of</strong> the bounding on a time scale, the research model<br />

makes explicit the phenomenon <strong>of</strong> embedding, a process which takes place over a<br />

period <strong>of</strong> time. <strong>The</strong> framework's social <strong>and</strong> relational constructs, such as the building<br />

<strong>of</strong> trust <strong>and</strong> reputations, <strong>and</strong> any resulting effects on the firm's organisational<br />

legitimacy in its local environment need to be seen in context <strong>and</strong> as enduring<br />

processes: they need time to be established, but may also be reversed over time by<br />

effect <strong>of</strong> the firm's activities.<br />

3.4.4 Case selection<br />

In the beginning <strong>of</strong> the empirical phase <strong>of</strong> data collection, the researcher needs to take<br />

the important decision on her samples, appropriate to provide meaningful insights in<br />

the course <strong>of</strong> the research process. To this effect “[n]othing is more important than<br />

making a proper selection <strong>of</strong> cases” (Stake, 1995: 243). <strong>The</strong> choice <strong>of</strong> case study<br />

objects may be driven by different purposes, such as the replication <strong>of</strong> previous cases,<br />

the extension <strong>of</strong> emergent theory, the filling <strong>of</strong> theoretical categories, or in order to<br />

provide examples <strong>of</strong> polar types (Eisenhardt, 1989; M. Miles & Huberman, 1994). In<br />

theory-building research, to which we attribute our research project, sample selection<br />

is conceptually driven, either by the theoretical framework which underpins the<br />

research question from the outset, or by an evolving theory which is derived<br />

inductively from the data as the research proceeds (Curtis, Gesler, Smith, &<br />

Washburn, 2000).<br />

Selection strategy. For an encompassing study <strong>of</strong> the research subject, the case study<br />

researcher must strategically select a case that is pertinent to the object <strong>of</strong> study, <strong>and</strong>


Empirical Approach<br />

which allows for sufficient access to relevant data, in order to obtain the desired<br />

insights. In addition to data access, the chosen object needs to show a potential <strong>of</strong><br />

being information-rich, as to permit an in-depth approach to uncover unexplored <strong>and</strong><br />

complex phenomena (Stake, 1995). In particular, cases should also provide the<br />

possibility to collect data on historical events, which Voss, Tsikriktsis, <strong>and</strong> Frohlich<br />

(2002) term retrospective cases. A purposeful <strong>and</strong> analytical case study selection<br />

therefore is decisive for the success <strong>of</strong> the research project, while “r<strong>and</strong>om selection is<br />

neither necessary, nor even preferable” (Eisenhardt, 1989: 537). Possible criteria for<br />

the purposeful case selection range from richness in information, to their being critical,<br />

revelatory, unique, or extreme (Stake, 1995) 19 . <strong>The</strong> objective <strong>of</strong> case study sampling is<br />

to identify those cases which help to exp<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> generalise theories, as opposed to just<br />

enumerate frequencies. In choosing case study objects, the researcher has to ensure,<br />

that apart from the generalisation-focus her attention also rests on the individual case.<br />

Overall, the purposeful selection <strong>of</strong> cases requires the researcher to be clear on two<br />

dimensions, i.e. she must have worked out an explicit sampling frame on the basis <strong>of</strong><br />

the research question <strong>and</strong> the research framework, <strong>and</strong> she needs to decide how many<br />

cases are needed in the analytic generalisations <strong>of</strong> the findings (M. Miles &<br />

Huberman, 1994; Yin, 1994).<br />

Within our dissertation we have chosen a mixed purposeful sampling strategy, which<br />

combines a number <strong>of</strong> strategies, for the purpose <strong>of</strong> triangulation <strong>and</strong> in order to meet<br />

multiple needs (Patton, 1990). More specifically, our sampling logic combines<br />

elements <strong>of</strong> intensity sampling, i.e. it focuses on information-rich cases that<br />

significantly manifest the phenomenon; criterion sampling, i.e. the interest lies in<br />

cases which meet some predetermined criteria <strong>of</strong> importance; <strong>and</strong> theory-based or<br />

operational construct sampling, i.e. the sampling <strong>of</strong> incidents on the basis <strong>of</strong> their<br />

potential manifestation <strong>of</strong> central theoretical constructs.<br />

Criteria for mixed purposeful sampling. <strong>The</strong> three case study objects that we have<br />

selected are all allocated within utility <strong>and</strong> concession-based industries (UCI). <strong>The</strong>y<br />

have been chosen on the basis <strong>of</strong> following sampling criteria:<br />

<strong>Location</strong>-fixity. All case study objects are infrastructure-heavy <strong>and</strong> rely on their<br />

specific location, either due to their need to be close to the market (market-based<br />

location-fixity), or due to their need for a local immobile resource (resource-based<br />

19 For more details on case selection criteria, see Patton (1990), who distinguishes between 16<br />

purposeful sampling strategies.<br />

53


54<br />

Empirical Approach<br />

location-fixity). For all <strong>of</strong> them location-dependence is grounded in their irreversible<br />

sunk investments.<br />

Geographical presence. <strong>The</strong> selected objects are all involved in multi-site operations.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se operations vary in geographical scale, with each case-study object representing<br />

one type <strong>of</strong> geographical diversification - global, international, <strong>and</strong> regional. In<br />

addition, the importance <strong>of</strong> the case study objects' cross-border operations in relation<br />

to their overall business differs significantly. <strong>The</strong>se variations serve to increase our<br />

findings' validity by analysing firms with differing resources for synergy exploitation<br />

in their multi-site activities.<br />

Strategic national importance. All selected case study objects are UCF, whose<br />

characteristics include the affiliation to an industry <strong>of</strong> strategic national importance,<br />

due to which they require a long-term concession from the state. <strong>The</strong>y all operate<br />

within a highly regulated environment, which impacts their scope <strong>of</strong> action.<br />

Related diversification: Importantly, the selected case study objects are related<br />

diversifiers. Particularly with regard to the multiple-unit perspective, we are interested<br />

in their opportunities for value creation <strong>and</strong> synergy realisation within their core<br />

business. We exclude those parts <strong>of</strong> the business from our scope <strong>of</strong> research, for which<br />

such synergy realisation with the core business is not applicable (e.g. the electricity<br />

trading unit in our power utilities case).<br />

Organisation type <strong>and</strong> ownership. All case study objects are limited companies, whose<br />

ownership structure ranges from fully private to fully state-owned. Two firms are<br />

organised as financial holdings, <strong>and</strong> one firm manages its multi-site activities by<br />

means <strong>of</strong> minority shareholdings <strong>and</strong> management contracts. While one firm is fully<br />

floated on the stock exchange, one is a mixed ownership firm with partial stateparticipation,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the third firm is a fully state-owned enterprise (SOE), despite its<br />

legal form as a limited company.<br />

Company culture. For all case study objects the cooperation between their sites, as<br />

well as between the site <strong>and</strong> the corporate parent 20 is either actively promoted or seen<br />

as a desirable state. In other words, the exploitation <strong>of</strong> synergies <strong>and</strong> inter-unit value<br />

creation forms part <strong>of</strong> these firms' operational objectives.<br />

20 For the case study object with minority shareholdings, the influence <strong>of</strong> the focal firm on the local<br />

site is based on a management contract, through which the firm has committed itself to the<br />

management <strong>and</strong> operation <strong>of</strong> the local site <strong>and</strong> thus has influence on the latter's performance.


Empirical Approach<br />

Accessibility <strong>of</strong> information In respect <strong>of</strong> the practical aspects <strong>of</strong> field research, all case<br />

study objects have a vital interest in the study results <strong>and</strong> signalled their openness<br />

regarding the access to key informants, relevant data <strong>and</strong> information.<br />

<strong>The</strong> decision to sample across three different industries has been driven by the<br />

objective to allow some generalisability <strong>of</strong> the results throughout the range <strong>of</strong> UCI,<br />

<strong>and</strong> to obtain insights if <strong>and</strong> in which regard the variation <strong>of</strong> the case objects matters.<br />

Case study objects. <strong>The</strong> three case study objects, which we identified through our<br />

purposeful sampling are<br />

- Axpo Group, one <strong>of</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong>’s leading power utilities<br />

- Holcim Ltd, one <strong>of</strong> the world’s largest suppliers <strong>of</strong> cement <strong>and</strong> aggregates<br />

- Flughafen Zürich AG, the operator <strong>of</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong>'s largest <strong>and</strong> Europe's 12 th<br />

largest airport in terms <strong>of</strong> annual passenger traffic<br />

Table 2-1 provides an overview on the case study objects on the individual dimensions<br />

for purposeful case selection.<br />

Axpo Holcim Zurich Airport<br />

Industry power utility building materials airport<br />

<strong>Location</strong>-fixity resource-based resource-based,<br />

market-based<br />

Geographical<br />

presence<br />

Strat. national<br />

importance<br />

Related<br />

diversification<br />

Regulatory<br />

environment<br />

Organisation<br />

type; subsidiary<br />

engagement<br />

Company<br />

culture<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong>,<br />

Europe<br />

High: central infrastructure<br />

for economy's functioning<br />

through electricity<br />

generation mix; coverage <strong>of</strong><br />

major parts <strong>of</strong> electricity<br />

supply chain<br />

resource-based,<br />

market-based<br />

global Switzerl<strong>and</strong>,<br />

international<br />

Medium: elementary to<br />

construction industry<br />

concrete <strong>and</strong><br />

construction materials<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, EU various various<br />

Ltd. company / holding,<br />

100% state-owned; mainly<br />

consolidated subsidiaries<br />

cooperative;<br />

synergy seeking<br />

Ltd. company / holding,<br />

publicly traded; mainly<br />

consolidated subsidiaries<br />

customer-oriented;<br />

synergy seeking<br />

Table 3-2: Overview case study objects <strong>and</strong> selection criteria<br />

55<br />

High: critical transport<br />

infrastructure<br />

airport operation,<br />

commerce <strong>and</strong> real<br />

estate management,<br />

consulting<br />

Ltd. company,<br />

38% state-owned;<br />

minority stakes<br />

cooperative, trusted,<br />

socially involved;<br />

synergy seeking


56<br />

3.5 Research process<br />

Empirical Approach<br />

<strong>The</strong> design <strong>of</strong> our research process consists <strong>of</strong> five analytic phases: research design,<br />

data ordering, data analysis, <strong>and</strong> literature comparison. <strong>The</strong>y are, in accordance with<br />

inductive research in general <strong>and</strong> with grounded theory in particular, not sequential but<br />

highly iterative <strong>and</strong> mutually reinforcing. In contrast to puritan versions <strong>of</strong> grounded<br />

theory, we have reverted to literature very early in our research process, as stipulated<br />

in the open-minded approach. This unfolding nature <strong>of</strong> our research <strong>and</strong> the<br />

interleaving research phases are illustrated in Figure 3-3.<br />

(1)<br />

Literature comparison<br />

Literature review<br />

(2)<br />

Research design<br />

• Familiarisation with research field<br />

• Deduction <strong>of</strong> research questions<br />

Research set-up & piloting<br />

(3)<br />

Data collection<br />

• Research structuring <strong>and</strong> planning<br />

• Informal conversations<br />

• Unstructured interviews<br />

• Testing <strong>of</strong> semi-structured interviews (4)<br />

Continuous comparison<br />

(4)<br />

Data ordering<br />

(5)<br />

Data analysis<br />

• Concept generation <strong>and</strong> clustering<br />

• Re-evaluation <strong>of</strong> interrelationships between categories<br />

• Subsumption into higher order categories<br />

Case research<br />

• Document review<br />

• Semi-structured interviews (22)<br />

Evaluation, recommendations<br />

• Description <strong>of</strong> emergent theory<br />

• Deduction <strong>of</strong> practical & theoretical<br />

implications, recommendations<br />

Jun 08 – Mar 09 Apr / May 09 Jun 09 – Sep 09 Oct 09 – Dec 09 Jan 10 – Dec 10<br />

Figure 3-3: Inductive research process<br />

In the first phase we have familiarised ourselves with the existing literature <strong>and</strong> the<br />

multiple perspectives, relevant to our research topic. In the initial months <strong>of</strong> our<br />

empirical process we have been able to formulate <strong>and</strong> refine our research questions,<br />

before moving on to the planning <strong>and</strong> structuring <strong>of</strong> our research. In addition, in line<br />

with continuous comparison in the grounded theory approach, we have consulted<br />

literature throughout our empirical research to ground <strong>and</strong> validate our empirical<br />

insights. With regard to the relevant research perspectives, we started with strategic


Empirical Approach<br />

management research (focusing on the resource-based theory) <strong>and</strong> organisation theory<br />

(in particular transaction cost economics), before moving on towards economic<br />

geography, <strong>and</strong> institutionalism (immersing in the fields <strong>of</strong> institutional economics <strong>and</strong><br />

economic sociology).<br />

Based on the findings <strong>of</strong> the literature review <strong>and</strong> the specified research questions, in<br />

the second phase we were able to start planning <strong>and</strong> structuring our research <strong>and</strong> the<br />

related case studies. We identified the case study objects <strong>and</strong> obtained their consent for<br />

participation in our research. By means <strong>of</strong> a piloting phase - including expert<br />

conversations, expert interviews, <strong>and</strong> four semi-structured test interviews - we<br />

established the interview guidance, which we continued to refine in the case research<br />

phase. As we gathered first empirical insights from the piloting, we also started with<br />

the continuous comparison <strong>of</strong> our data with prior insights <strong>and</strong> with the relevant<br />

literature.<br />

<strong>The</strong> third phase served to gather empirical insights in view <strong>of</strong> our research questions.<br />

We conducted 22 semi-structured interviews, identifying our informants by means <strong>of</strong><br />

theoretical sampling. While the first half <strong>of</strong> the interviews served to obtain new<br />

insights, we increasingly shifted our focus on the validation <strong>of</strong> our findings from prior<br />

interviews. Thus, we were able to add focus to our questions, dig deeper into those<br />

arrays, where we needed further clarification, to extend our research framework with<br />

additional relevant constructs, <strong>and</strong> to exclude initial presumptions which could not be<br />

confirmed in these interviews. This process continued, until we felt that no significant<br />

additional insights could be gained, presuming to have reached saturation. Throughout<br />

this phase, we documented our cases along the emerging structure <strong>of</strong> our research<br />

framework.<br />

While we advanced with our information collection, we also intensified our data<br />

ordering efforts, thus proceeding into the fourth phase <strong>of</strong> our research. Building on the<br />

data densification <strong>of</strong> the ongoing comparison process, our endeavours to sense-making<br />

resulted not only in a consistent research framework, but also in an in-depth<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the characteristics <strong>and</strong> specifications <strong>of</strong> the individual parts there<strong>of</strong>.<br />

Consequently, in the fifth <strong>and</strong> final phase we formulated propositions <strong>and</strong> immersed in<br />

a cross-comparison <strong>of</strong> the case study findings, in order to identify similarities <strong>and</strong><br />

differences, <strong>and</strong> thus to strengthen the external validity <strong>of</strong> our findings. In one instance<br />

we identified a relevant construct, but could not condense the insights into one logical<br />

explanation (i.e. the influence <strong>of</strong> the competitive environment on the firm's<br />

institutional exposure). As a consequence, we formulated a set <strong>of</strong> alternative <strong>and</strong><br />

57


58<br />

Empirical Approach<br />

partially contradictory propositions, the clarification <strong>of</strong> which would require further<br />

analysis in a future research project. After having described the emerging theory, we<br />

finalised our research by deriving the conclusions <strong>and</strong> the relevant practical <strong>and</strong><br />

theoretical implications <strong>of</strong> our findings, as well as our recommendations for future<br />

research.<br />

3.6 Methods<br />

Methods are the instruments for implementation <strong>of</strong> the research design. Under<br />

consideration <strong>of</strong> the internal validity <strong>and</strong> the requirements <strong>of</strong> inductive research,<br />

typically multiple data collection methods <strong>and</strong> data sources are combined (Eisenhardt,<br />

1989). In the following sections we will describe the methods employed in our<br />

research, including the means <strong>and</strong> sources <strong>of</strong> data collection.<br />

3.6.1 Expert discussions <strong>and</strong> semi-structured interviews<br />

Interviews are an effective way to gather rich, empirical data, particularly useful in<br />

researching intermittent phenomena (Eisenhardt & Graebner, 2007), such as the<br />

process <strong>of</strong> embedding or local exposure. For our empirical research, we have used this<br />

data gathering channel by interviewing experts from different levels <strong>of</strong> hierarchy (i.e.<br />

from top tier managers to specialists with relevant background <strong>and</strong> experience),<br />

different geographies (including interview partners based in South Asia, Eastern<br />

Europe, the Caucasus, <strong>and</strong> Western Europe), <strong>and</strong> from outside our case study objects<br />

(e.g. from the public administration) in order to provide an additional perspective on<br />

our research <strong>and</strong> as a means for validation.<br />

Overall, we conducted a total <strong>of</strong> 26 interviews, with 22 informants, all <strong>of</strong> which lasted<br />

between one <strong>and</strong> two-<strong>and</strong>-a-half hours. In four cases we had the possibility to revert to<br />

the interviewee at a later stage <strong>of</strong> the empirical phase, in order to assess the fields <strong>of</strong><br />

interest in more depth <strong>and</strong> to clarify additional particulars. <strong>The</strong> list <strong>of</strong> our interview<br />

partners <strong>and</strong> the details on time <strong>and</strong> purpose <strong>of</strong> the exchange are provided in the<br />

Annexure.<br />

With regard to our interviewing sequence, we have started out with a series <strong>of</strong> expert<br />

discussions in order to better bound our field <strong>of</strong> research <strong>and</strong> to increase our focus. In a<br />

pilot-run we conducted four semi-structured interviews with representatives from<br />

Zurich Airport, respectively the affiliated Bangalore International Airport, <strong>and</strong> with<br />

Axpo Group with the objective to refine the interview structure <strong>and</strong> to increase the<br />

relevance <strong>and</strong> precision <strong>of</strong> the questions. <strong>The</strong>reby we improved the output quality <strong>of</strong>


Empirical Approach<br />

the later case interviews, which we conducted throughout our empirical research<br />

phase. An example <strong>of</strong> the interview outlines for the semi-structured interviews is<br />

included in the Annexure.<br />

Prior to the interview, all informants were provided with an introduction to the<br />

research topic, as well as the guiding questions at least two days in advance. In the<br />

beginning <strong>of</strong> the exchange they were informed on the interview procedures.<br />

Furthermore, they consented to our expressed request to record <strong>and</strong> transcribe the<br />

interview (see also next passage). Within ten days <strong>of</strong> the exchange, the interviewee<br />

received a transcript for review in respect <strong>of</strong> the statements' accuracy <strong>and</strong> for further<br />

comments. All transcripts, but one 21 , have finally been released to be used for our<br />

research <strong>and</strong> for direct quotation.<br />

As we progressed in our empirical phase, we gradually changed the purpose <strong>of</strong> the<br />

interviews which have been arranged on the basis <strong>of</strong> theoretical sampling:<br />

- Piloting & refining <strong>of</strong> the interview guide: four interviews, in the beginning <strong>of</strong><br />

the empirical phase<br />

- Gathering <strong>of</strong> rich <strong>and</strong> thick data: 12 interviews to substantiate the initial<br />

simplified framework <strong>and</strong> to collect insights on the attributes <strong>of</strong> the constructs<br />

- Refining <strong>and</strong> validating <strong>of</strong> research model: 12 interviews in the second half <strong>of</strong><br />

the empirical phase to further specify <strong>and</strong> confirm the identified constructs <strong>and</strong><br />

related attributes<br />

By employing theoretical sampling, we were able to explore the gathered data <strong>and</strong> the<br />

identified concepts in depth. Due to the sampling being responsive to the data, each<br />

event could build on previous data <strong>and</strong> analysis, thus contributing to the subsequent<br />

data collection <strong>and</strong> analysis (Corbin & Strauss, 2008). This process continued until we<br />

were able to reach the point <strong>of</strong> saturation, i.e. until no new evidence emerged which<br />

could meaningfully contribute to the theory building.<br />

21 From one interviewee no final feedback on the transcript could be obtained. We therefore refrained<br />

from direct quotations.<br />

59


60<br />

Questions<br />

Data<br />

collection<br />

Concepts<br />

Saturation<br />

Analysis<br />

all concepts well<br />

defined <strong>and</strong> explained<br />

Figure 3-4: <strong>The</strong>oretical sampling process to saturation<br />

Empirical Approach<br />

3.6.2 Data transcription<br />

During the first phase <strong>of</strong> the empirical research, data analysis serves to reduce <strong>and</strong><br />

interpret the collected information. This process is facilitated by means <strong>of</strong> transcription<br />

<strong>of</strong> the conducted interviews (Morse & Richards, 2002), which have the additional<br />

advantage <strong>of</strong> documenting the data gathering. Transcriptions thereby add to the<br />

transparency <strong>of</strong> the research process <strong>and</strong> consequently increase the internal validity <strong>of</strong><br />

the research. <strong>The</strong> transcription system should be pragmatically chosen, serving the<br />

purpose <strong>of</strong> being “easy to write, easy to read, easy to learn <strong>and</strong> easy to search” (Flick,<br />

2009: 300). Based on this premise, we have chosen a combination <strong>of</strong> literal<br />

transcription, as well as selective transcription (cf. Höld, 2007) to ensure optimal data<br />

evaluation. More precisely, approximately half <strong>of</strong> the interviews were transcribed in<br />

their whole length. Over time, <strong>and</strong> with increasing clarity <strong>and</strong> focus, we decided to<br />

transcribe selectively <strong>and</strong> to omit passages which did not contribute to the research<br />

framework, neither through new insights nor through confirmation <strong>of</strong> prior gained<br />

insights.<br />

3.6.3 Document analysis<br />

In addition to the insights from the interviews, our in-depth analysis <strong>of</strong> the case study<br />

objects was complemented by written documents from various sources. Apart from<br />

publicly available company information, such as annual reports, brochures, or<br />

company web sites, we also had access to internal communication that added to the<br />

internal validity <strong>and</strong> the cases' richness. In addition, we collected data from the press<br />

<strong>and</strong> media, analyst reports, electronic sources (databases, internet, etc.), <strong>and</strong> other<br />

publicly available material. <strong>The</strong>se additional information sources served the


Empirical Approach<br />

clarification <strong>of</strong> data which we received in the interviews, <strong>and</strong> provided additional<br />

insights into the firm's culture, its approach to corporate social responsibility (CSR)<br />

<strong>and</strong> stakeholder interaction, <strong>and</strong> its st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>of</strong> corporate governance. It also helped to<br />

verify <strong>and</strong> detail anecdotal evidence, respectively provided an external view on this<br />

evidence through media coverage.<br />

3.6.4 Protocols <strong>and</strong> documentation<br />

<strong>The</strong> use <strong>of</strong> protocols for the documentation <strong>of</strong> the research process represents an<br />

important tactic towards increasing research reliability (Yin, 1994). We therefore have<br />

made use <strong>of</strong> documentation by means <strong>of</strong> a case study protocol, through memoing, <strong>and</strong><br />

by keeping a research log-book, all <strong>of</strong> which will be briefly described below.<br />

Case study protocol. A case study or research protocol is a means to foster the<br />

creative process, helping to capture a maximum <strong>of</strong> relevant insights from the collected<br />

data. In addition to the specification <strong>of</strong> the employed research instruments, the central<br />

element <strong>of</strong> the case study protocol is the guide to the interviews. We formulated the<br />

initial interview guidance throughout the pilot phase <strong>of</strong> our interviews <strong>and</strong> continued<br />

to refine it as we progressed. For each conducted interview, we have documented the<br />

individual guidance, an example <strong>of</strong> which is included in the Annexure.<br />

Logbook <strong>and</strong> memoing. Another element with regard to the reliability <strong>of</strong> our research<br />

is the use <strong>of</strong> a research log-book, which documents the progress <strong>of</strong> the research <strong>and</strong> the<br />

process <strong>of</strong> building theory from the gathered data. Notes with regard to our train <strong>of</strong><br />

thought, the condensing <strong>of</strong> data, <strong>and</strong> the transformation there<strong>of</strong> into the emergent<br />

theory have been documented throughout the dissertation project. More complex<br />

insights in the process <strong>of</strong> continuous comparison have been documented by means <strong>of</strong><br />

memoing, segregated into memos <strong>of</strong> theoretical <strong>and</strong> methodological relevance, as well<br />

as deliberations <strong>and</strong> comments on the research topic.<br />

Case study database. For full documentation on the research process <strong>and</strong> to establish<br />

transparency on the research materials which we gathered <strong>and</strong> used, a case study<br />

database contains all documents related to a case study. We have established such a<br />

database in the form <strong>of</strong> a suitable virtual folder structure <strong>and</strong> have stored our collected<br />

case study documents accordingly.<br />

3.6.5 Coding <strong>and</strong> analysis<br />

Data analysis is “working with data, organising it, breaking it into manageable units,<br />

synthesising it, searching for patterns, discovering what is important <strong>and</strong> what is to be<br />

61


62<br />

Empirical Approach<br />

learned, <strong>and</strong> deciding what you will tell others” (Bogdan & Biklen, 1982: 145). At the<br />

heart <strong>of</strong> grounded theory analysis is the coding process, through which concepts are<br />

extracted from raw data, “developing them in terms <strong>of</strong> their properties <strong>and</strong><br />

dimensions” (Corbin & Strauss, 2008: 159). With the help <strong>of</strong> coding strategies the<br />

collected data is broken down into units <strong>of</strong> meaning <strong>and</strong> rearranged into concepts <strong>and</strong><br />

higher-order categories (Goulding, 1998), thus providing the means by which the<br />

emerging theory can be integrated.<br />

As described in sub-chapter 3.5 we have ordered <strong>and</strong> analysed data throughout our<br />

data gathering phase <strong>and</strong> beyond, a process which has been greatly facilitated by the<br />

use <strong>of</strong> coding. <strong>The</strong>reby, coding did not only support our analytical process, but also<br />

served an organisational purpose (Bazeley & Richards, 2000). As recommended by<br />

grounded theory methodology, we frequently moved between open coding, the writing<br />

<strong>of</strong> memos, axial coding, <strong>and</strong> modelling throughout our empirical process. In the<br />

analysis <strong>of</strong> our interview data we started coding already in the course <strong>of</strong> the<br />

transcription process (i.e. open coding). In this phase, we broke down the gathered<br />

data into distinct units <strong>of</strong> meaning, which enables the researcher to describe what is<br />

happening in the data (Goulding, 2002). Consequently, we attributed the identified<br />

categories with properties, defined as characteristics that are common to all the<br />

concepts in the category (Goede & De Villiers, 2003) <strong>and</strong> dimensions. In the ensuing<br />

phase <strong>of</strong> axial coding we reduced the number <strong>of</strong> codes, <strong>and</strong> developed the<br />

relationships among them.<br />

3.7 Research quality<br />

In order to verify the quality <strong>of</strong> inductive research, similarly to quantitative research a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> logical tests are generally established <strong>and</strong> agreed. Generally, verification in<br />

qualitative research refers to mechanisms during the research process, which<br />

incrementally contribute to ascertaining the reliability (relating to the possibility that<br />

the operations <strong>of</strong> a study can be repeated generating the same findings), <strong>and</strong> validity<br />

(as the extent to which any measuring instrument measures what it is intended to<br />

measure), <strong>and</strong> consequently the rigour <strong>of</strong> a study (Morse, Barrett, Mayan, Olson, &<br />

Spiers, 2002). In addition, qualitative research needs to be objective, i.e. it must be free<br />

from arbitrariness <strong>and</strong> r<strong>and</strong>omness, value judgements, <strong>and</strong> ideology, <strong>and</strong> it must be<br />

utilitaristic inasmuch as the results must be accomplished in an economically efficient<br />

<strong>and</strong> justifiable way (Göthlich, 2003). Through consequent consideration <strong>of</strong> these<br />

mechanisms in every step <strong>of</strong> the inquiry, the researcher is able to produce a solid


Empirical Approach<br />

output. Importantly, these mechanisms ensure that errors are identified <strong>and</strong> corrected<br />

before they negatively affect the developing research framework or the related<br />

analysis.<br />

Generally, the assessment <strong>of</strong> validity <strong>and</strong> reliability in inductive research is faced with<br />

two major challenges: First <strong>of</strong> all, the methods <strong>of</strong> qualitative research are not<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ardised <strong>and</strong> results therefore are derived through interpretation <strong>of</strong> data by the<br />

researcher, which makes it difficult to ensure the research's reliability <strong>and</strong> validity.<br />

Secondly, the findings are highly context-related - a deliberate feature <strong>of</strong> qualitative<br />

research - which makes it more difficult to generalise the insights, <strong>and</strong> thus lowers<br />

their external validity. <strong>The</strong> subsequent sections will address these challenges <strong>and</strong><br />

further specify the measures <strong>of</strong> quality which mitigate them. Furthermore, we will<br />

describe how we integrated these considerations in our research.<br />

3.7.1 Validity<br />

In qualitative research validity is considered as the central issue in order to ascertain<br />

research quality, as it is concerned with the degree to which the research supports the<br />

researcher's conclusions (Bortz & Döring, 2006). <strong>The</strong>reby three different types <strong>of</strong><br />

validity are distinguished, namely construct validity, internal validity, <strong>and</strong> external<br />

validity:<br />

- Construct validity is concerned with the quality <strong>of</strong> the operationalisation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

relevant concept<br />

- Internal validity refers to the extent to which the findings accurately describe<br />

reality, <strong>and</strong> to the establishing <strong>of</strong> causal relationships between the constructs<br />

- External validity refers to the extent to which the findings may be generalised<br />

across different settings<br />

In the ongoing scientific debate on the ideal measures <strong>of</strong> quality in inductive research,<br />

validity is also referred to as credibility or dependability.<br />

Construct validity. Construct validity is satisfied, if the researcher has identified the<br />

right constructs <strong>and</strong> their operationalisation for the chosen research subject. It can be<br />

ensured through a number <strong>of</strong> tactics in the data collection process, including (1) the<br />

use <strong>of</strong> multiple sources <strong>of</strong> evidence, (2) establishing a chain <strong>of</strong> evidence, <strong>and</strong> (3) the<br />

reviewing <strong>of</strong> the draft case study report through key informants (Denzin & Lincoln,<br />

2000; Göthlich, 2003; Yin, 1994). With regard to the data collection process in our<br />

case studies, all three tactics have been deliberately employed <strong>and</strong> made transparent,<br />

mainly in the present chapter, as outlined subsequently.<br />

63


64<br />

Empirical Approach<br />

(1) Multiple sources <strong>of</strong> evidence. <strong>The</strong> case study approach as research method<br />

explicitly foresees the use <strong>of</strong> multiple data sources. In our dissertation we have<br />

employed a number <strong>of</strong> sources, by interviewing 22 relevant informants within <strong>and</strong><br />

outside our three case-study objects, <strong>and</strong> by drawing on internal <strong>and</strong> on external<br />

documents.<br />

(2) Chain <strong>of</strong> evidence. Pertaining to the establishment <strong>of</strong> a clear chain <strong>of</strong> evidence, Yin<br />

(1994) recommends four measures to be taken. First <strong>of</strong> all, there should be abundant<br />

reference in the report to the relevant case study data by means <strong>of</strong> citation. We have<br />

satisfied this condition throughout our case study report, as well as in the theorybuilding<br />

chapter <strong>of</strong> our dissertation. In addition, the researcher needs to collect all<br />

evidence in a structured way, such as to be able to reveal it when asked to, <strong>and</strong> she<br />

should indicate the specific circumstances under which data collection took place,<br />

which we did in section 3.6.1. Third, the researcher needs to maintain a case study<br />

protocol, including the description <strong>of</strong> the specific procedures <strong>and</strong> questions used<br />

during the data gathering process. Our use <strong>of</strong> protocols <strong>and</strong> log-books throughout the<br />

empirical phase is described in section 3.6.4. Ultimately, this protocol needs to<br />

indicate, how it is linked to the initial research questions, which we also ensured. For<br />

documentation, we have added a case study protocol in the Annexure.<br />

(3) Review through key informants. By letting key informants review the transcripts <strong>of</strong><br />

the exchange, as well as the resulting case study report, construct validity may be<br />

strengthened (Yin, 1994). For all three case study objects, informants have had the<br />

possibility to review the case, which they did at minimum with regard to the direct<br />

quotations. At least one key informant for each case object has reviewed the entire<br />

case study in respect <strong>of</strong> accuracy <strong>of</strong> the information, as well as with regard to logical<br />

consistency.<br />

Internal validity. This aspect <strong>of</strong> validity, also known as logical validity, ascertains if<br />

the relation between two variables is properly demonstrated, respectively if the related<br />

arguments are compelling enough to defend the conclusions drawn from the research.<br />

Different from construct validity, internal validity is established throughout the data<br />

analysis phase <strong>of</strong> the research (Yin, 1994). Although establishing internal validity is<br />

not easy for inductive research, <strong>and</strong> for case studies in particular, the researcher may<br />

employ a number <strong>of</strong> strategies to this effect, including (1) the a priori definition <strong>of</strong><br />

research questions, (2) triangulation, <strong>and</strong> (3) pattern-matching (Eisenhardt, 1989; Yin,<br />

1994), as outlined subsequently.


Empirical Approach<br />

(1) A priori definition <strong>of</strong> research questions. Defining research questions <strong>and</strong> a priori<br />

constructs in the beginning <strong>of</strong> the research is beneficial with regard to the researcher's<br />

focus <strong>and</strong> provides a better grounding <strong>of</strong> construct measures (Eisenhardt, 1989). We<br />

have defined our research questions in the initial phase <strong>of</strong> our research, when we<br />

started to review literature <strong>and</strong> before immersing in the empirical phase. However,<br />

research questions <strong>and</strong> preliminary constructs necessarily remained tentative <strong>and</strong> were<br />

refined throughout our research.<br />

(2) Triangulation. Defined as “the combination <strong>of</strong> methodologies in the study <strong>of</strong> the<br />

same phenomenon” (Denzin, 1978: 291), triangulation reflects “an attempt to secure<br />

an in-depth underst<strong>and</strong>ing” (Denzin & Lincoln, 2003: 8) <strong>of</strong> this phenomenon. It<br />

addresses the issue <strong>of</strong> internal validity by seeking multiple sites <strong>and</strong> levels for studying<br />

the research subject. Its basic principle is applicable to four major areas: method<br />

triangulation, data triangulation, theory triangulation, <strong>and</strong> researcher triangulation<br />

(Creswell & Miller, 2000). <strong>The</strong> triangulation <strong>of</strong> methods represents its strongest form<br />

(Flick, 2007). Although we have applied only inductive data collection methods, we<br />

have been able to triangulate within <strong>and</strong> between methods (Denzin, 1978) by<br />

employing different interviewing methods, <strong>and</strong> by the additional review <strong>of</strong> documents.<br />

With regard to data triangulation, the differentiation <strong>of</strong> the three dimensions <strong>of</strong> time,<br />

space <strong>and</strong> individuals is <strong>of</strong> relevance (Flick, 2007). More precisely, the analysis <strong>of</strong> the<br />

phenomenon should take place at different points in time, at different places <strong>and</strong> with<br />

different individuals. We have satisfied the criteria for data triangulation particularly<br />

through the use <strong>of</strong> theoretical sampling (see also sections 3.4.2 <strong>and</strong> 3.5), but also by<br />

studying documents which cut across several years <strong>of</strong> the companies' recent history,<br />

<strong>and</strong> different geographical <strong>and</strong> organisational parts <strong>of</strong> the case study objects. <strong>The</strong><br />

triangulation <strong>of</strong> theories has been considered, as we have chosen a multi-lens<br />

approach, trying to ground our research framework in the fields <strong>of</strong> strategic<br />

management research, economic geography, institutionalism, as well as economic<br />

sociology. Thus, we have tied our emergent theory to existing literature from those<br />

research areas, thereby further enhancing the internal validity, generalisability, <strong>and</strong><br />

theoretical level <strong>of</strong> theory building from case study research (Eisenhardt, 1989).<br />

Lastly, on the dimension <strong>of</strong> researcher triangulation, internal validity is rather fragile,<br />

as we discussed our work with other researchers on an irregular frequency, based on<br />

the need for exchange <strong>and</strong> reflection throughout the research process.<br />

65


66<br />

Dimensions <strong>of</strong> triangulation Satisfied Comment<br />

Method � use <strong>of</strong> 2 inductive methods<br />

Data � theoretical sampling; differentiation on the<br />

dimensions <strong>of</strong> time, space <strong>and</strong> individuals<br />

Empirical Approach<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory � multi-lens approach; established links between<br />

research framework <strong>and</strong> existing theories<br />

Researcher ~ individual researcher, sporadic need-based discussion<br />

with other researchers<br />

� adequately satisfied; ~ weakly satisfied<br />

Table 3-3: Internal validity through triangulation<br />

(3) Pattern Matching. <strong>The</strong> logic <strong>of</strong> pattern matching “compares an empirically based<br />

pattern with a predicted one” (Yin, 1994: 106), whereby coinciding patterns strengthen<br />

the internal validity <strong>of</strong> the case study <strong>and</strong> its results (Trochim, 1989). In explanatory<br />

case-studies, these patterns should be related to the independent or the dependent<br />

variables <strong>of</strong> the research framework. Among the different approaches to pattern<br />

matching (for more details see also Yin, 1994), we have employed an explanationbuilding<br />

strategy which iteratively compares the findings from cases with the initial<br />

propositions - an approach also in line with grounded theory. In addition, we have<br />

selectively used the logic <strong>of</strong> rival explanations as patterns, whereby in one instance we<br />

have not been able to rule out individual rivalling rationales: while interviewed<br />

representatives from the case study objects agreed on the importance <strong>of</strong> the firm's<br />

'competitive environment' as a moderating variable in our research framework, no<br />

saturation could be reached with regard to the directions <strong>of</strong> its effects. In this particular<br />

case we have theoretically <strong>and</strong> empirically grounded the rivalling explanations <strong>and</strong><br />

derived several mutually exclusive propositions there<strong>of</strong>, which require further<br />

verification in future research.<br />

External validity. Concerned with the context within which the research findings can<br />

be applied, external validity refers to the degree <strong>of</strong> a study's generalisability. Due to<br />

the idiosyncratic circumstances <strong>of</strong> case studies, external validity represents a major<br />

hindrance in the application <strong>of</strong> case study research <strong>and</strong> remains a source <strong>of</strong> criticism<br />

with regard to the research method. <strong>The</strong>re are two strategies to increase the external<br />

validity <strong>of</strong> findings in case study research: once more theoretical sampling <strong>and</strong> the<br />

cross-comparison <strong>of</strong> cases.


Empirical Approach<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical sampling. Different from the statistical generalisation <strong>of</strong> quantitative<br />

research, case study research relies on analytical generalisation, whereby the<br />

researcher endeavours to generalise a particular set <strong>of</strong> results to broader theory<br />

(Eisenhardt, 1989; Yin, 1994). For this purpose the right sampling strategy is essential.<br />

<strong>The</strong> use theoretical sampling, as already described previously in this chapter, thereby<br />

helps to increase the external validity <strong>of</strong> research by choosing cases which make the<br />

relevant process transparently observable, respectively which are likely to replicate the<br />

emergent theory, or to discover categories, properties, <strong>and</strong> interrelationships that will<br />

extend the theory.<br />

Cross-case comparison. Another strategy to increase external validity is the searching<br />

for patterns across the cases. To this purpose, the choice <strong>of</strong> case study objects must<br />

follow replication logic, in the sense that for each chosen object the researcher expects<br />

the same results (Yin, 1994). Thus, the collected evidence becomes more compelling,<br />

respectively the overall study gains in robustness. In accordance with this logic, we<br />

have chosen three case study objects with the expectation to find similarities on the<br />

dimensions <strong>of</strong> our research framework. <strong>The</strong>refore, such as to increase our results'<br />

external validity we have not only performed a within-case analysis, but also<br />

compared the three cases against each other.<br />

3.7.2 Reliability<br />

<strong>The</strong> concept <strong>of</strong> reliability is also known as dependability within qualitative research.<br />

Determining the extent to which other researchers are able to arrive at the same<br />

insights at a later point (Denzin & Lincoln, 2000), it is concerned with the two issues<br />

<strong>of</strong> whether the research questions are clear with congruent features in the study design;<br />

<strong>and</strong> whether the research has been carried out with reasonable care (Riege, 2003). By<br />

working towards high reliability, the researcher therefore aims at minimising the errors<br />

<strong>and</strong> possible biases throughout the research. Among the strategies to increase the<br />

reliability <strong>of</strong> results, Yin (1994) recommends the (1) diligent documentation <strong>of</strong><br />

research procedures, as provided by means <strong>of</strong> the present chapter, the case study<br />

protocol in the annexure, <strong>and</strong> our research log-book; (2) the case study database,<br />

which contains all collected documents, interview transcripts <strong>and</strong> other information<br />

related to the cases - as described in section 3.6.4; <strong>and</strong> (3) the establishment <strong>of</strong> a chain<br />

<strong>of</strong> evidence, as already outlined in the section 3.7.1 on research validity.<br />

67


68<br />

3.8 Conclusion<br />

Empirical Approach<br />

On the basis <strong>of</strong> a post-positivistic research paradigm <strong>and</strong> in accordance with the<br />

contextual nature <strong>of</strong> our research subject, we have chosen an inductive research<br />

strategy in order to find answers to our research questions. Since previous research so<br />

far seems to have neglected the adequate conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> location-fixity,<br />

respectively the latter's effects on firms' value creation, we consider this dissertation as<br />

contributing to theory. Accordingly, we have applied the qualitative research methods<br />

<strong>of</strong> case study <strong>and</strong> grounded theory research, due to their explorative character, which<br />

supports the generation <strong>of</strong> new insights. Further arguments, supporting our choice <strong>of</strong><br />

methods, are their theory building character, which facilitates the grounding <strong>and</strong><br />

additional specification <strong>of</strong> our core construct, <strong>and</strong> their interpretive <strong>and</strong> inductive<br />

character, easing the comprehension <strong>of</strong> complex theoretical assertions. More<br />

specifically, we have employed an embedded multiple case design, selecting three case<br />

study objects along the logic <strong>of</strong> a mixed purposeful sampling strategy, in which we<br />

combined elements <strong>of</strong> intensity sampling, criterion sampling, <strong>and</strong> theory-based or<br />

operational construct sampling. By winning three ideal case study objects which<br />

classify as UCF, our case portfolio allows to follow a replication logic, while ensuring<br />

sufficient variation on a number <strong>of</strong> dimensions to increase the findings' external<br />

validity. <strong>The</strong>se case study objects are Flughafen Zürich AG, Axpo Group <strong>and</strong> Holcim<br />

Ltd.<br />

Moreover, we imparted high importance to the goodness <strong>of</strong> research through<br />

transparent documentation <strong>of</strong> how we arrived at the findings <strong>and</strong> conclusions, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

research process in general. Additionally the use <strong>of</strong> triangulation on various<br />

dimensions served to enhance the study's validity. Through the two strategies <strong>of</strong><br />

constant comparison <strong>and</strong> theoretical sampling, as promoted by the grounded theory<br />

approach, we were able to gather thick <strong>and</strong> rich information. <strong>The</strong> resulting insights<br />

were verified to the point <strong>of</strong> saturation <strong>and</strong> ultimately condensed by means <strong>of</strong> different<br />

stages <strong>of</strong> coding. In summary, we therefore believe to have employed adequate<br />

measures to ensure rigour in our research, <strong>and</strong> to arrive at robust <strong>and</strong> valid results.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

4 <strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

In the present chapter we will outline a relational model on location-fixity, its effects<br />

on firms, <strong>and</strong> its consequences on firms' value creation opportunities. Built on a multilens<br />

perspective, our framework draws on strategic management research, economic<br />

geography, economic sociology, as well as institutional economics. It acknowledges<br />

the role <strong>of</strong> institutions in economic life, as well as the importance <strong>of</strong> relations between<br />

the economic actors. <strong>The</strong> latter are seen in the light <strong>of</strong> methodological individualism,<br />

which stresses the preferences, objectives, ideas <strong>and</strong> motivations <strong>of</strong> individuals. Thus,<br />

society, the state, firms <strong>and</strong> political parties are not regarded as collective actors, but as<br />

a bundle <strong>of</strong> individual actors (cf. Richter & Furubotn, 2003). Preluding to our research<br />

framework, we begin with a general conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> space, scale <strong>and</strong> location as a<br />

basis for the ensuing definition <strong>of</strong> the location-fixity construct. Besides, we will briefly<br />

draw on institution theory for a conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> institutions, introducing a<br />

contextual view <strong>of</strong> the firm in its local environment, before further elaborating the<br />

research framework.<br />

4.1 Space, place <strong>and</strong> scale<br />

In conceptualising location-fixity <strong>and</strong> the embeddedness <strong>of</strong> firms in their local<br />

environment, it is crucial to distinguish between different concepts <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

geography, such as space, place <strong>and</strong> scale. While space relates to physical distance <strong>and</strong><br />

area, the concept <strong>of</strong> place refers to the specificity <strong>of</strong> particular places that are carved<br />

out <strong>of</strong> space. Through the notion <strong>of</strong> place, economic processes are being explored<br />

under consideration <strong>of</strong> the environmental, social, cultural, institutional <strong>and</strong> political<br />

contexts in which they are embedded (Coe et al., 2007). In this contextual approach<br />

firms <strong>and</strong> their environment are assumed to influence each other significantly by their<br />

interaction. Finally the concept <strong>of</strong> scale organises places through a typology <strong>of</strong> spatial<br />

scales, typically ranging from the local, regional, national a macro-regional to the<br />

global scale.<br />

69


70<br />

Space<br />

Place<br />

Scale<br />

distance / area<br />

context<br />

reach<br />

Figure 4-1: Conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> space, place <strong>and</strong> scale<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

<strong>The</strong> location, respectively the place where a firm chooses to settle in order to take up<br />

its activities is a crucial success factor. Contingent on the kind <strong>of</strong> resources which are<br />

critical for the firm, its criteria for choosing a location will differ. <strong>Location</strong> factors, in<br />

the sense <strong>of</strong> “variable location-specific conditions, influences <strong>and</strong> forces etc., which<br />

have a positive or negative effect on the development <strong>of</strong> a production site” (Mikus,<br />

1978, as cited in Zöller, 2004: 61), therefore determine a firm's choice <strong>of</strong> location.<br />

Such considerations include (Maier & Tödtling, 2006):<br />

- Upstream. Availability <strong>and</strong> access to a company's critical resources (l<strong>and</strong>,<br />

labour, capital, natural resources, semi-finished products, know-how, <strong>and</strong><br />

technology)<br />

- Downstream. Access to relevant markets<br />

- Factors relevant on the up- <strong>and</strong> downstream side. Infrastructure with public<br />

good character, <strong>and</strong> agglomeration advantages<br />

With view at our research object, utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based firms, particularly the<br />

tangible <strong>and</strong> immobile upstream factors are relevant, because <strong>of</strong> their dependence on<br />

local resource inputs - mostly in the form <strong>of</strong> natural resources. For operators <strong>of</strong><br />

hydropower plants, for example, suitable water deposits <strong>and</strong> -flows are decisive for<br />

their location choice, whereas for extractive industries the deposits <strong>of</strong> respective<br />

natural resources determine their options. Looking downstream, some <strong>of</strong> these<br />

industries additionally depend on the proximity to their customers. In other words,<br />

their market reach is limited on a spatial scale, as exemplified by the cement industry,<br />

which is affected by high product transportation costs, or airports, which need to be<br />

within the reach <strong>of</strong> a catchment area. This particular importance <strong>of</strong> location factors for<br />

UCFs is one <strong>of</strong> the cornerstones in the development <strong>of</strong> our research framework.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

4.2 Institutions<br />

In order to set the context <strong>of</strong> our research framework, the following section provides a<br />

brief introduction to institution theory <strong>and</strong> develops our underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> institutions.<br />

Institutions are omnipresent in our society <strong>and</strong> economy, as they are “the systems <strong>of</strong><br />

established <strong>and</strong> prevalent social rules that structure social interaction” (Hodgson,<br />

2006: 2). More precisely, within institutional theory they represent organised interests,<br />

which are “ordered collections <strong>of</strong> rules, laws, regulations, property rights, habits,<br />

practices, customs <strong>and</strong> routines that are enforced <strong>and</strong> that enable, guide <strong>and</strong> normalise<br />

relations <strong>and</strong> behaviour among various parties” (Jovanovic, 2009: 154). For conceptual<br />

clarity, it is important to differentiate between institutions <strong>and</strong> organisations. <strong>The</strong> latter<br />

are established in an institutional environment, <strong>and</strong> - once they are created - also<br />

develop institutions <strong>of</strong> their own (e.g. company culture). <strong>The</strong>se organisation-specific<br />

institutions tend to set the formal <strong>and</strong> informal “rules” <strong>of</strong> how to act <strong>and</strong> behave in the<br />

different positions within them. Lundequist (as cited in Dale & Nilsen, 2000: 4)<br />

applies a metaphor for a clearer distinction: whereas organisations can be seen as the<br />

players, institutions represent the rules <strong>of</strong> the play. Both mutually influence each other:<br />

organisations by the way the institutions (rules) are formulated, <strong>and</strong> the formal <strong>and</strong><br />

informal rules by the organisations' (the players') activities. In a market context, the<br />

institutional environment sets the formal <strong>and</strong> informal rules for governance <strong>of</strong> the<br />

economy (Storper, 1997), supporting the creation <strong>and</strong> 'proper' orientation <strong>of</strong> market<br />

forces, economic growth <strong>and</strong> development. <strong>The</strong> resulting effects are stability in<br />

economic interaction <strong>and</strong> the reduction <strong>of</strong> uncertainty <strong>and</strong> transaction costs.<br />

4.2.1 Pillars <strong>of</strong> institutions<br />

Despite the efforts to clarify the institutional term within institutions theory, it is still<br />

in many ways ambiguous. With the objective to distinguish the divergent conceptions<br />

more clearly, Scott (2001) introduced three dimensions, i.e. the regulative, normative<br />

<strong>and</strong> cognitive pillar <strong>of</strong> institutions. <strong>The</strong> regulative pillar <strong>of</strong> institutions refers to<br />

processes such as rule setting, monitoring, <strong>and</strong> sanctioning activities. Within this<br />

perspective, economic actors orient their behaviour on the basis <strong>of</strong> costs <strong>of</strong> rewards<br />

<strong>and</strong> penalties, in other words rules are obeyed because it is the actor’s self-interest to<br />

conform. <strong>The</strong> regulative pillar is particularly emphasised by economists, whose<br />

classical conception <strong>of</strong> economic behaviour discerns individuals <strong>and</strong> organisations<br />

primarily as pursuing their self-interest through instrumental, utilitarian behaviour. In<br />

contrast, institutions on the normative dimension impose constraints on social<br />

behaviour, while at the same time empowering <strong>and</strong> enabling social action. Thus,<br />

71


72<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

institutions prescribe rights <strong>and</strong> privileges as well as responsibilities <strong>and</strong> duties<br />

(expressing, “what is expected <strong>of</strong> me”). Finally, the cognitive pillar stresses the way<br />

situations are framed <strong>and</strong> social identities defined (Scott, 2001). It centres on the<br />

question <strong>of</strong> sense-making, i.e. our conception <strong>of</strong> who we are <strong>and</strong> what actions make<br />

sense to us in given situations. In short, the cognitive dimension <strong>of</strong> institutions<br />

embodies our things 'taken for granted'. Table 4-1 provides an overview on the<br />

characteristics <strong>and</strong> delimitation <strong>of</strong> the three pillars.<br />

Regulative Normative Cognitive<br />

Basis <strong>of</strong> compliance expedience social obligation taken for grantedness,<br />

shared underst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

Basis <strong>of</strong> order regulative rules binding expectations constitutive schema<br />

Mechanisms coercive normative mimetic<br />

Logic instrumentality appropriateness orthodoxy<br />

Indicators rules, laws, sanctions certification,<br />

accreditation<br />

common beliefs,<br />

shared logics <strong>of</strong> action<br />

Basis <strong>of</strong> legitimacy legally sanctioned morally governed comprehensible,<br />

recognisable, culturally<br />

supported<br />

Table 4-1: Three pillars <strong>of</strong> institutions 22<br />

Scott's separation <strong>of</strong> the normative <strong>and</strong> the cognitive pillar is not entirely definite, with<br />

the three pillars being mutually reinforcing, thus weaving into a strong social<br />

framework. As a consequence, from the regulative to the cognitive pillar there is a<br />

continuum “from the conscious to the unconscious, from the legally enforced to the<br />

taken for granted” (H<strong>of</strong>fman, 2001: 36).<br />

Within our research framework all three pillars are relevant with regard to the<br />

conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> firms' embeddedness in their institutional environment, as well as<br />

firms' perception <strong>of</strong> their role <strong>and</strong> responsibilities within this environment. Pertaining<br />

to UCF, the regulative underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> institutions is essential, due to the high<br />

importance <strong>of</strong> regulation within the related industries. <strong>The</strong>refore, firms may rightly<br />

view institutions from a utilitarian perspective, perceiving them as means to create<br />

stability for the firm’s economic activities, <strong>and</strong> which they need to respect also in<br />

22 Scott, 2001.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

order protect themselves from any immediate <strong>and</strong> tangible consequences <strong>of</strong> noncompliance<br />

with rules. Nonetheless, the normative <strong>and</strong> cognitive dimensions <strong>of</strong><br />

institutions are equally relevant, in order to maintain the firm's social acceptance<br />

within its environment, since “organisations require more than material resources <strong>and</strong><br />

technical information if they are to survive <strong>and</strong> thrive in their social environments.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y also need social acceptability <strong>and</strong> credibility” (Scott & al., as cited in Scott,<br />

2001: 58). <strong>The</strong>se contextual aspects are <strong>of</strong> primary importance in our framework.<br />

4.2.2 Institutional environment <strong>and</strong> institutional arrangements<br />

Two levels <strong>of</strong> analysis apply within institutional economics concerning the relations<br />

between firms <strong>and</strong> institutions: the institutional environment on a macro level, <strong>and</strong><br />

institutions <strong>of</strong> governance on a micro level. Davis <strong>and</strong> North (1971: 133) define the<br />

institutional environment as a “set <strong>of</strong> fundamental political, social, <strong>and</strong> legal ground<br />

rules that govern economic <strong>and</strong> political activity”, such as rules governing elections,<br />

property rights, <strong>and</strong> the rights <strong>of</strong> contract. Institutions <strong>of</strong> governance or institutional<br />

arrangements on the other h<strong>and</strong> may be <strong>of</strong> a formal or informal character <strong>and</strong> are<br />

understood as “an arrangement between economic units that govern the ways in which<br />

these units can cooperate or compete” (ibid.).<br />

Combined with the effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity, both, the firm's institutional environment<br />

<strong>and</strong> its institutions <strong>of</strong> governance are central factors for its value creation capacity<br />

within our research framework. If the overall institutional environment encourages a<br />

firm's self-responsible demeanour, the firm can use its internal governance capacity (in<br />

the sense <strong>of</strong> trust-building) to lower transaction costs in its interactions with the<br />

environment.<br />

4.2.3 Institutions <strong>and</strong> economic performance<br />

<strong>The</strong> availability, quality <strong>and</strong> enforcement <strong>of</strong> institutions are crucial for the<br />

coordination <strong>and</strong> the consistency <strong>of</strong> actions in an economy. Institutions provide the<br />

incentive structure <strong>of</strong> an economy, <strong>and</strong> their direction <strong>of</strong> evolution shapes the long-run<br />

economic performance. Depending on how institutions reward productive activities,<br />

firms will engage to grow, thus benefiting the overall economy. From a firmperspective,<br />

an institutional environment that encourages trust among trading<br />

partners 23 may facilitate the creation <strong>of</strong> relational rents (S. Zaheer, 1995). Strong<br />

institutional presence, however, seems to run along a utility curve whose marginal<br />

23 I.e. an institutional environment with effective 'rules' or social controls for enforcing agreements.<br />

73


74<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

utility turns negative at a certain point. Amin <strong>and</strong> Thrift (1994) suggest that too much<br />

'institutional thickness' 24 can turn firms resistant to change, consequently inhibiting<br />

learning, innovation <strong>and</strong> growth. Despite this note <strong>of</strong> caution <strong>and</strong> in view <strong>of</strong> the<br />

characteristics <strong>of</strong> our research object, institutional embeddedness in our research<br />

framework is primarily regarded as critical to UCFs' survival, i.e. the more<br />

institutionally embedded they are in their local environment, the more gainful for the<br />

firm.<br />

4.2.4 Institutional distance - the liability <strong>of</strong> foreignness<br />

An interesting approach to the challenges <strong>of</strong> firms operating in non-familiar<br />

institutional contexts is <strong>of</strong>fered by the 'liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness' concept, originating<br />

from S. Zaheer (1995). Firms engaging outside their home-territory face such<br />

liabilities, as a consequence <strong>of</strong> not underst<strong>and</strong>ing the local environment <strong>and</strong><br />

institutional practices, <strong>and</strong> due to a lack <strong>of</strong> legitimacy (Xu & Shenkar, 2002). For<br />

multi-site firms that engage in different institutional contexts it is therefore critical to<br />

be able to bridge institutional distances between the host <strong>and</strong> home environment for<br />

sustained competitive advantage (Van de Ven, 2004). While the observable elements<br />

<strong>of</strong> the liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness are quite well researched, it is probably the more tacit<br />

elements that considerably affect firms' performance in negative ways (Cox & Mair,<br />

1988: 308). <strong>The</strong> concept <strong>of</strong> liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness <strong>and</strong> firms' capability to embed<br />

themselves in host environments will be taken up again in our research framework<br />

with regard to multi-site firms (see sub-chapter 4.10).<br />

<strong>The</strong> next section elaborates our research questions <strong>and</strong> provides an overview on the<br />

research framework.<br />

4.3 Conceptual framework development<br />

During the exploratory phase <strong>of</strong> our research, a basic framework for location-fixity<br />

<strong>and</strong> its effects on firms' value creation opportunities has emerged. In the course <strong>of</strong> this<br />

process our attention has shifted in two regards, based on the insights gained. On a<br />

theoretical level, the initial assumption that the construct <strong>of</strong> location-fixity has been<br />

sufficiently researched <strong>and</strong> defined has proven to be too optimistic. Despite extensive<br />

literature research in the fields <strong>of</strong> strategic management (triggered by the construct <strong>of</strong><br />

24 <strong>The</strong> authors define institutional thickness as "the combination <strong>of</strong> factors including inter-institutional<br />

interaction <strong>and</strong> synergy, collective representation by many bodies, a common industrial purpose, <strong>and</strong><br />

shared cultural norms <strong>and</strong> values" (ibid: 15).


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

site-specificity), as well as economic geography (following various streams <strong>of</strong> location<br />

theory <strong>and</strong> new economic geography) the therein established terms <strong>and</strong> definitions<br />

appeared to be ambiguous. As a consequence, the first research question – “what is<br />

location-fixity?” - needed to be more thoroughly researched than initially expected, as<br />

its importance for our dissertation increased. <strong>The</strong>refore, the subsequent discussion <strong>of</strong><br />

location-fixity forms the basis for approaching the subsequent research questions.<br />

Secondly, on the empirical level, the indications from our expert interviews in the<br />

various case studies consistently pointed towards the importance <strong>of</strong> firms' embedding<br />

into their local environment as a response to location-fixity. In our case studies, firms'<br />

long-term commitment to a location was accompanied by management's awareness <strong>of</strong><br />

the importance <strong>of</strong> embedding efforts, including active stakeholder management,<br />

lobbying activities, as well as pro-active communication towards the local community.<br />

Thus, in order to better underst<strong>and</strong> the effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity from a single-site<br />

perspective, we shifted our initial emphasis on the relationships between multiple sites<br />

<strong>of</strong> location-bound firms more towards exploring the link between location-fixity <strong>and</strong><br />

value creation <strong>of</strong> single sites, under consideration <strong>of</strong> their institutional environment.<br />

As a result to these shifts in emphasis, we have decided to split the research questions<br />

<strong>and</strong> framework in two parts, first <strong>of</strong> all exploring location-fixity <strong>and</strong> value creation in<br />

the firm's single-site context, before concentrating on multi-site set-ups in the second<br />

part.<br />

4.3.1 Research questions guiding the framework development<br />

<strong>The</strong> initial impulse for the research topic came from the author's pr<strong>of</strong>essional<br />

experience in the international business development <strong>of</strong> airports, as the important<br />

issue, if airport operators' engagements at geographically dispersed sites create value<br />

evoked ambiguous judgements from experts in the field. Thus, after preliminary<br />

research, including exchanges with industry pr<strong>of</strong>essionals <strong>and</strong> researchers, we<br />

identified the characteristic <strong>of</strong> location-fixity as one <strong>of</strong> the central differentiating<br />

criteria that made the question <strong>of</strong> value contribution difficult to answer. In comparison<br />

to manufacturing firms, an airport has limited opportunities to optimise the value chain<br />

<strong>of</strong> its daily operation across multiple sites, <strong>and</strong> compared to service industries it cannot<br />

relocate <strong>and</strong> build its business elsewhere once a commitment to a site has resulted in<br />

infrastructure development. Starting from this angle, we generalised the construct <strong>of</strong><br />

location-fixity, identifying other affected industries with similar set-ups. As a result,<br />

we delimited our research object to all firms in industries which are characterised by<br />

heavy infrastructure investments, high regulation density, <strong>and</strong> long planning cycles<br />

75


76<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

summarising them as 'Utilities <strong>and</strong> Concession-bound Industries' (UCI). After an<br />

enlightening process <strong>of</strong> literature review <strong>and</strong> exchanges with practitioners, our<br />

research questions emerged <strong>and</strong> were sharpened over time, as elaborated below.<br />

(I) Single-unit perspective. <strong>The</strong> construct <strong>of</strong> location-fixity to date is not clearly<br />

defined in its characteristics <strong>and</strong> effects for firms. Consequently, it is <strong>of</strong> interest to<br />

clarify this ambiguity first by elaborating these elements, the sources, <strong>and</strong> the resulting<br />

dependencies <strong>of</strong> location-fixity. This results in our first research question:<br />

Research Question 1: What is location-fixity?<br />

- What are the elements <strong>of</strong> location-fixity?<br />

- Which kinds <strong>of</strong> dependence stem from location-fixity?<br />

- Which external factors further influence the effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity?<br />

- What are the characteristics <strong>of</strong> location-fixity for utilities <strong>and</strong> concession bound<br />

industries (UCI)?<br />

In conjunction with the first research question, the subsequent question arises as to the<br />

effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity on the research object. Notably, location-fixity constitutes<br />

many forms <strong>of</strong> dependence, particularly on the firm's local environment <strong>and</strong> on its<br />

stakeholders. <strong>The</strong>se various dependencies are consolidated in the construct <strong>of</strong><br />

institutional exposure, which is derived directly from location-fixity. In turning our<br />

attention on the effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> the resulting institutional exposure, we<br />

will explore the next question <strong>and</strong> sub-questions as follows:<br />

Research Question 2: How do location-fixity <strong>and</strong> the related institutional exposure<br />

affect utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based firms (UCF)?<br />

- What is institutional exposure?<br />

- What are the sources <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure?<br />

- What are the limitations <strong>and</strong> opportunities from institutional exposure?<br />

Taking the constructs <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> related institutional exposure together, we<br />

subsume them under the term 'local exposure' in our research framework. This local<br />

exposure is assumed to affect UCFs' value creation in a number <strong>of</strong> ways, which to<br />

explore is the objective <strong>of</strong> the next research question.<br />

Research Question 3:How does the resulting local exposure affect UCFs' value<br />

creation?<br />

After the exploration <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> its various effects on UCFs, research<br />

question four focuses on the firm's action parameters, i.e. the possibilities at h<strong>and</strong> to


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

take influence on the effects <strong>of</strong> local exposure. In our efforts to explore the action<br />

parameters we analyse the different elements firms have at h<strong>and</strong> to embed themselves<br />

sustainably at a location, to reduce their exposure <strong>and</strong> in some cases to turn the effects<br />

<strong>of</strong> location-fixity into a value creating advantage.<br />

Research Question 4:How can firms mitigate the effects <strong>of</strong> local exposure?<br />

- What kind <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities do firms need?<br />

- How can these embedding capabilities change local exposure in valueenhancing<br />

ways?<br />

(II) Multi-site perspective. Turning towards the initial focus <strong>of</strong> the research project,<br />

the second part <strong>of</strong> the framework is concerned with the possibilities <strong>of</strong> value creation<br />

between multiple sites <strong>of</strong> the UCF, respectively between the UCF's headquarters<br />

(corporate centre) <strong>and</strong> its geographically dispersed subsidiaries.<br />

In comparison with footloose manufacturing firms UCFs have fewer opportunities to<br />

optimise the different elements <strong>of</strong> their supply <strong>and</strong> value chains. On the basis <strong>of</strong> this<br />

rationale we try to carve out the differences, respectively the limitations that locationfixity<br />

puts on multi-site management, resulting in the next research question:<br />

Research Question 5: How does location-fixity impact UCFs' multi-site resource<br />

management?<br />

In view <strong>of</strong> the spatial limitations <strong>of</strong> UCF research question six elaborates on the<br />

remaining value creation opportunities in multi-site management, respectively on<br />

opportunities which base on the identified limitations. Thus we derive sub-questions as<br />

listed below:<br />

Research Question 6: How can multi-site UCF create value under the condition <strong>of</strong><br />

local exposure?<br />

- What roles <strong>and</strong> functions can the corporate centre play to increase overall value<br />

creation through its multi-site engagement?<br />

- In which fields are location-bound units able to cooperate among each other <strong>and</strong><br />

create value?<br />

- How can the corporate centre create value by helping its local units to overcome<br />

liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness?<br />

77


78<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

<strong>The</strong> last research question is concerned with the insights from both parts <strong>of</strong> the<br />

framework, with the aim <strong>of</strong> drawing conclusions on further implications <strong>of</strong> the<br />

findings.<br />

Research Question 7: What are the theoretical <strong>and</strong> practical implications for<br />

companies with location-fixed assets?<br />

In section 4.4 we will commence to outline the first part <strong>of</strong> our research framework,<br />

before theoretically grounding <strong>and</strong> empirically developing the individual elements in<br />

more detail.<br />

4.4 Part one - embedded single unit perspective<br />

In the process <strong>of</strong> our empirical research the embeddedness <strong>of</strong> the research object in its<br />

local environment developed into a key element <strong>of</strong> our research framework. As a<br />

consequence <strong>of</strong> this cognisance our theoretical orientation altered slightly <strong>and</strong> led to a<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>ound review <strong>of</strong> literature from the fields <strong>of</strong> economic geography, institutionalism<br />

<strong>and</strong> economic sociology, besides the literature in strategic management research. Most<br />

importantly, integrating the notion <strong>of</strong> embeddedness in our framework led to a<br />

conceptual valorisation <strong>of</strong> the firm's local context in which it performs its activities. As<br />

a result <strong>of</strong> our empirical insights, we therefore postulate that a firm's local<br />

embeddedness, as “the way in which organisations or actors become tied in to the local<br />

business <strong>and</strong> institutional environment” (Alderman, 2004: 256), has implications for<br />

its value creation opportunities. This notion is illustrated by the following statement <strong>of</strong><br />

an executive <strong>of</strong> Axpo (interview N°1: 12), who asserts that “local embeddedness is the<br />

central factor for us - all our plants <strong>and</strong> facilities depend on the local approval. We feel<br />

that this factor is becoming increasingly important”. In setting the notion <strong>of</strong><br />

embeddedness in context with the core construct <strong>of</strong> location-fixity, we established the<br />

'institutional exposure' construct which reflects the firm's dependency on its local<br />

environment <strong>and</strong> its need to be locally embedded. In a further attempt to simplify the<br />

framework, we subsumed 'location-fixity' <strong>and</strong> 'institutional exposure' under the<br />

concept <strong>of</strong> 'local exposure'. As a starting point for the framework development in the<br />

subsequent sections, Figure 4-2 illustrates the simplified model <strong>and</strong> establishes the<br />

links between the main constructs. For better orientation, the sub-chapters which<br />

further develop the constructs are indicated in parentheses.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

structural (economic) (4.8.4)<br />

relational (social) (4.8.5)<br />

local exposure from<br />

embedding<br />

capabilities (4.8)<br />

moderate<br />

location fixity (4.5 - 4.7) value creation (4.9)<br />

influences<br />

location fixity (4.5)<br />

strategic options (4.9.2)<br />

constitutes<br />

business risks (4.9.3)<br />

institutional exposure (4.6)<br />

operational (4.11.4)<br />

Figure 4-2: Simplified conceptual framework <strong>and</strong> references to subchapters<br />

Starting from these main constructs, we will now incrementally detail the notions <strong>of</strong><br />

the research framework <strong>and</strong> derive related propositions, progressing from the left to<br />

the right side <strong>of</strong> our framework. In this process some <strong>of</strong> the developed notions will<br />

require deliberate theoretical grounding, particularly due to the chosen multi-lens<br />

approach. Such excurses will be distinguished as such, consistently leading back to the<br />

framework's main structure.<br />

4.4.1 Central links <strong>and</strong> notions <strong>of</strong> the research framework<br />

Our research framework develops from the core construct <strong>of</strong> location-fixity (cf. section<br />

4.5), a characteristic to the firm which causes an increased dependence on its local<br />

environment. With reference to Jovanovic's (2009) definition <strong>of</strong> institutions as<br />

'organised interests', this dependence in the form <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure subsumes<br />

the claims, dem<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> expectations <strong>of</strong> the firm's local stakeholders. It is the degree<br />

to which a firm is exposed <strong>and</strong> vulnerable to these claims, depending on its<br />

geographical flexibility to avoid them.<br />

Leaning on the terminology <strong>and</strong> basic concepts <strong>of</strong> transaction cost theory, the<br />

institutional exposure from location-fixity derives from potential opportunism on the<br />

side <strong>of</strong> the firm's stakeholders. It is therefore assumed, that the firm's spatial<br />

immobility is adversely influencing its bargaining power, consequently having an<br />

impact on the distribution <strong>of</strong> the firm's created economic rent. As the firm commits<br />

itself to a location for the long-term, e.g. through site-specific assets, it becomes prone<br />

to hold-up situations 25 from its local environment with the objective to appropriate its<br />

25 For more details on the hold-up problem, see for example Richter & Furubotn (2003), or Hart &<br />

Moore (1990).<br />

79


80<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

quasi-rents. Such hold-up experiences are illustrated by the following example from<br />

our empirical research: In the negotiations between the power utility Axpo <strong>and</strong> a local<br />

public administration on the subject <strong>of</strong> a thermal power plant, Axpo had to accept the<br />

redistribution <strong>of</strong> a significant share <strong>of</strong> its rents. A member <strong>of</strong> the firm's senior<br />

management reflects: “they [the administration] know exactly that the national<br />

regulation requires us to achieve a certain heat utilisation ratio, attainable only by the<br />

delivery <strong>of</strong> electricity plus long-distance heating. In the course <strong>of</strong> the negotiation for<br />

the pricing <strong>of</strong> long-distance heat we were forced to settle for a price less than half <strong>of</strong><br />

the benchmark price for domestic fuel oil” (interview N°3: 7). Consequently, the first<br />

proposition suggests a relationship between location-fixity <strong>and</strong> institutional exposure<br />

as follows:<br />

Proposition 1<br />

<strong>The</strong> higher a firm's location-fixity, the higher its institutional exposure <strong>and</strong> risk <strong>of</strong> rent<br />

appropriation by its local stakeholders.<br />

As illustrated in Figure 4-2, the two constructs 'location-fixity' <strong>and</strong> 'institutional<br />

exposure' combined represent the firm's overall 'local exposure'. It is important to note,<br />

that this construct summarises the firm's potential exposure in the sense <strong>of</strong> an overall<br />

map <strong>of</strong> eventual risks, which are rooted in the firm's location-fixity. In case such risks<br />

materialise, however, they may affect the firm's ability to create value - reflected by<br />

the uni-directional relation between local exposure <strong>and</strong> value creation in our<br />

framework. <strong>The</strong> firm's endeavours to reduce its exposure <strong>and</strong> the possible effects on its<br />

value creation are aggregated in the 'embedding capabilities' construct, which entails<br />

capabilities towards the economic <strong>and</strong> relational embedding <strong>of</strong> the firm. Inherent to<br />

these capabilities is the aim to endow the firm with a high degree <strong>of</strong> 'organisational<br />

legitimacy', a concept borrowed from institutional theory <strong>and</strong> further elaborated in<br />

section 4.8.2. By building such legitimacy, understood as acceptance <strong>of</strong> the<br />

organisation by its environment (Kostova & Zaheer, 1999), the firm ensures a<br />

fundamental congruence between stakeholders' expectations <strong>and</strong> the firm's fulfilment<br />

there<strong>of</strong>. In other words, by developing capabilities to achieve such legitimisation the<br />

firm may mitigate the negative impacts <strong>of</strong> its local exposure. As illustrated by our case<br />

study object Holcim, such awareness <strong>of</strong> the importance <strong>of</strong> local embedding can<br />

become a critical success factor. <strong>The</strong> firm maintains in a company-internal fact-sheet<br />

“that earning <strong>and</strong> keeping the trust <strong>and</strong> respect <strong>of</strong> our stakeholders […] is not only a<br />

prerequisite for our licence to operate, but will fundamentally strengthen our business”


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

(Holcim Ltd., 2007). <strong>The</strong> second proposition therefore relates to the influence <strong>of</strong><br />

organisational legitimacy on the link between the firm's local exposure <strong>and</strong> its value<br />

creation.<br />

Proposition 2<br />

<strong>The</strong> potential negative impact <strong>of</strong> local exposure on the firm's value creation is<br />

moderated by its capabilities to embed itself locally.<br />

Now that the main constructs <strong>and</strong> their links within the simplified research framework<br />

are established, the following subchapters will elaborate the model <strong>and</strong> the thereto<br />

related notions. To this objective we start with the conceptual clarification <strong>of</strong> the<br />

framework's core construct 'location-fixity', in accordance with our first research<br />

question.<br />

4.5 <strong>Location</strong>-fixity<br />

In our endeavour to conceptually clarify the notion <strong>of</strong> location-fixity, <strong>and</strong> based on our<br />

empirical research, we distinguish three types <strong>of</strong> location-fixity: resource-based,<br />

market-based <strong>and</strong> ownership-based, which will be specified in more detail in the<br />

ensuing sub-chapters, as referenced in Figure 4-3.<br />

embedding<br />

capabilities (4.8)<br />

local exposure from<br />

moderate<br />

location fixity (4.5 - 4.7) value creation (4.9)<br />

influences<br />

location fixity (4.5)<br />

constitutes<br />

resource-based (4.5.1)<br />

market-based (4.5.2)<br />

ownership-based (4.5.3)<br />

institutional exposure (4.6)<br />

Figure 4-3: Types <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> corresponding references to subchapters<br />

<strong>The</strong> first <strong>and</strong> most obvious type, the resource-based location-fixity, is based on the<br />

firm's upstream dependencies. In other words, the firm's spatial immobility is the result<br />

<strong>of</strong> its dependence on natural resources which are critical, scarce <strong>and</strong> locality-specific,<br />

or it stems from a dependence on tangible assets, i.e. locality-specific infrastructure<br />

81


82<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

that involves sunk cost <strong>and</strong> site-specific assets. Frequently, both dependencies<br />

coincide, e.g. when firms develop infrastructure to exploit the locality-specific<br />

resources. Secondly, looking downstream, firms may equally become dependent on a<br />

location due to the non-substitutability <strong>of</strong> their localised exchange linkages (Cox &<br />

Mair, 1988), i.e. the firm's reliance on stable buying <strong>and</strong> selling relationships.<br />

Alternatively, such market-based location-fixity may arise from the nature <strong>of</strong> the firm's<br />

product, which requires its spatial proximity to customers, e.g. due to limited product<br />

transportability. Lastly, location-fixity may be ownership-based, implying constraints<br />

through the firm's shareholders. In the case <strong>of</strong> state-owned enterprises (SOE), or firms<br />

with state participation, for instance, spatial restrictions may arise when the<br />

shareholder's utility function is determined by factors other than pr<strong>of</strong>it-maximisation.<br />

Table 4-2 summarises the types, associated characteristics <strong>and</strong> dependencies <strong>of</strong><br />

location-fixity <strong>and</strong> provides examples within utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based industries.<br />

Type<br />

Dep.<br />

Characteristics Examples<br />

Resource-based (upstream)<br />

Natural resource dependence 26<br />

<strong>Local</strong>ity-specific natural resource deposit:<br />

<strong>The</strong> firm relies on critical <strong>and</strong> scarce<br />

resources, which cannot be obtained from<br />

other localities, <strong>and</strong> which are either nontransferable<br />

or controlled by other locally<br />

dependent actors who are not willing to<br />

relocate themselves nor the resource.<br />

Resources in this context mostly signify<br />

natural resources, including l<strong>and</strong>.<br />

(continued on next page)<br />

Hydropower: waterways with hydro<br />

potential<br />

Airport: l<strong>and</strong> development around<br />

perimeter<br />

Cement: limestone quarry<br />

Seaport: waterways navigable for cargo<br />

traffic, located nearby agglomerations<br />

Skiing resorts: skiable slopes <strong>and</strong><br />

infrastructural access<br />

Oil production: exploitable & accessible<br />

oil deposit<br />

Railway: coherent l<strong>and</strong> resource for nondisrupted<br />

railway line<br />

26 This operationalisation is in line with the resource dependence theory, which postulates resource<br />

dependence to exist, when the firm relies on resource supply which is marked by (1) concentration, (2)<br />

controllability, (3) non-mobility, (4) non-substitutability, <strong>and</strong> (5) essentiality (cf. Frooman, 1999).


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Type<br />

Dep.<br />

Tangible asset dependence<br />

Characteristics Examples<br />

Long-term sunk investments:<br />

Irrevocable commitment <strong>of</strong> the firm to a site<br />

through a substantial investment in assets<br />

limited to a particular use, <strong>and</strong> therefore not<br />

recoverable in case <strong>of</strong> exit.<br />

Assets in this context include tangible assets,<br />

such as plants <strong>and</strong> other infrastructure, as<br />

well as intangible assets, as property rights<br />

<strong>and</strong> concessions.<br />

Market-based dependence (downstream)<br />

Dependence on market<br />

proximity<br />

Dependence on local<br />

customer relationship<br />

Product-related customer-proximity:<br />

<strong>The</strong> pursuance <strong>of</strong> the object <strong>of</strong> a firm requires<br />

its vicinity to the customer, due to the nature<br />

<strong>of</strong> the product.<br />

<strong>The</strong> required proximity to the market can be<br />

evoked by the nature <strong>of</strong> the product, as in the<br />

case <strong>of</strong> services, or by economically<br />

prohibitive product transportation cost.<br />

Customer-related tie-up to location:<br />

<strong>The</strong> location <strong>of</strong> the firm was chosen on<br />

grounds <strong>of</strong> co-location with the customer or<br />

service partner.<br />

Sunk cost commitments tie the firm to the<br />

location, site- respectively relationshipspecific<br />

assets tie it to the local customer.<br />

Ownership dependence<br />

Dependence on owners'<br />

utility function<br />

Significance <strong>of</strong> public shareholder:<br />

<strong>The</strong> interests <strong>of</strong> (a fraction <strong>of</strong>) the firm's<br />

shareholders deviate from pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

maximisation.<br />

A public shareholder can add to the firm's<br />

location-fixity because benefits through<br />

presence in the region outweigh pr<strong>of</strong>itability<br />

gains through involvement at different<br />

locations.<br />

Table 4-2: Types <strong>and</strong> characteristics <strong>of</strong> location-fixity<br />

Hydropower: hydroelectric turbines, dam<br />

wall installations<br />

Airport: runway system, apron &<br />

taxiways<br />

Cement: mining & quarry infrastructure<br />

Seaport: container terminals, docks,<br />

yards, warehousing infrastructure<br />

Skiing resorts: ski lifts, funiculars, hotel<br />

infrastructure<br />

Oil production: oil rigs & platforms<br />

Railway: rail system<br />

Airport: proximity to catchment area<br />

(passengers, cargo-inducing industry)<br />

Cement: proximity to construction market<br />

(economically viable radius <strong>of</strong> app. 100<br />

km)<br />

Railway infrastructure: proximity to<br />

catchment area (passengers, cargoinducing<br />

industry)<br />

Seaport: dependence <strong>of</strong> terminal operator<br />

on port authority/operator<br />

Airport: dependence <strong>of</strong> maintenance,<br />

repair <strong>and</strong> overhaul providers on airport's<br />

functionality <strong>and</strong> attractiveness<br />

Airport, railway infrastructure, seaport:<br />

strategic relevance for regional economic<br />

development to attract further businesses<br />

Power generation, water utilities:<br />

strategic relevance due to enabling<br />

capacity for functioning <strong>of</strong> all other<br />

economic activity<br />

83


84<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

With reference to our research object, resource-based location-fixity practically always<br />

applies to utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based industries, owing to their sunk cost<br />

commitments. By contrast, market-based location-fixity is less prevalent, only<br />

affecting a subset <strong>of</strong> these industries. Ownership-based location-fixity frequently<br />

applies to UCI, since their strategic importance for local economies commonly goes<br />

along with state-involvement. Considering the thus gained insights, we define<br />

location-fixity as follows:<br />

Definition <strong>of</strong> location-fixity<br />

<strong>The</strong> circumstance <strong>of</strong> being tied to a specific location on account <strong>of</strong> resource-, market-<br />

<strong>and</strong>/or ownership-based dependencies.<br />

4.5.1 Resource-based location-fixity<br />

Defined rather generically, resources are inputs into the firm's production process. Any<br />

economic enterprise is dependent on resource inputs from its environment, be they<br />

tangible or intangible. However, the availability <strong>and</strong> abundance <strong>of</strong> resource inputs may<br />

vary significantly, with some <strong>of</strong> them being scarce <strong>and</strong> competed over by different<br />

economic players. Not surprisingly, therefore, resource dependence theory views<br />

resources as a basis <strong>of</strong> power. Consequently, the scarcer a resource <strong>and</strong> the more<br />

important it is for the firm's activities, the higher is the resulting uncertainty <strong>of</strong> a firm<br />

if it lacks control thereover. Thus, firms seek ways to control <strong>and</strong> exploit these critical<br />

resources in order to reduce their uncertainty <strong>and</strong> to ensure survival.<br />

Resources within the RBV. Within the RBV resources are defined as to “include all<br />

assets, capabilities, organisational processes, firm attributes, information, knowledge,<br />

etc. controlled by a firm that enable the firm to conceive <strong>of</strong> <strong>and</strong> implement strategies<br />

that improve its efficiency <strong>and</strong> effectiveness” (Daft, 1983, as cited in Barney, 1991:<br />

101). Stated more simply “resources are the tangible <strong>and</strong> intangible assets <strong>of</strong> a firm<br />

which can be drawn upon by the firm when required to achieve its objective(s)” (Ray<br />

& Ramakrishnan, 2005: 4). In the firm's efforts to generate differentially greater value,<br />

it relies on critical resources as “those factors that have a significant positive effect on<br />

either the economic costs or perceived benefits associated with an enterprise’s<br />

products” (Peteraf & Barney, 2003: 316). Furthermore, its overall resource<br />

configuration is decisive with regard to attaining sustainable competitive advantage.<br />

To this end the firm must also possess strategic resources, which have to be valuable,<br />

rare, imperfectly imitable <strong>and</strong> imperfectly substitutable (the so-called VRIN criteria,


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Barney, 1991). Since these characteristics must be fulfilled simultaneously strategic<br />

resources typically are intangible (cf. Amit & Schoemaker, 1993; Michalisin, Smith, &<br />

Kline, 1997), as “fixed-assets, like plant <strong>and</strong> equipment which can be purchased <strong>of</strong>fthe-shelf<br />

by all industry participants, cannot be the source <strong>of</strong> a firm's competitive<br />

advantage” (Teece et al., 1997: 518).<br />

Resource dependence within the scope <strong>of</strong> the research model. Resource-based<br />

immobility <strong>of</strong> firms evidently originates from those resources which are locationbound,<br />

i.e. difficult or impossible to relocate. <strong>The</strong>se might be <strong>of</strong> tangible <strong>and</strong><br />

intangible nature, as illustrated in Figure 4-4 which grades resources along the<br />

dimensions <strong>of</strong> mobility <strong>and</strong> tangibility. This view corresponds with conceptualisations<br />

in economic geography, wherein local dependence is defined as the dependence on a<br />

resource which is critical to a firm's operation <strong>and</strong> to which it needs access as a<br />

necessary condition for its operation (Oinas, 1998).<br />

spatial mobility<br />

−<br />

+<br />

knowledge<br />

(explicit)<br />

skills<br />

reputation<br />

knowledge<br />

(tacit, embedded)<br />

culture<br />

concessions,<br />

property rights<br />

−<br />

1 2<br />

3 4<br />

tangibility<br />

labour<br />

machinery<br />

other equipment<br />

l<strong>and</strong><br />

plants<br />

natural resource<br />

deposit<br />

Figure 4-4: Immobility-inducing resources<br />

+<br />

With reference to the nature <strong>of</strong> our research object, as infrastructure heavy,<br />

concession-dependent <strong>and</strong> highly regulated businesses, such resources critical to the<br />

firm's operation include: scarce <strong>and</strong> excludable natural resources, tangible assets <strong>and</strong><br />

thereto related sunk cost commitments, <strong>and</strong> on the intangible dimension a concession<br />

to operate, respectively particular property rights. Often UCF also are characterised<br />

through critical tacit knowledge, which is embedded in the organisation as a result <strong>of</strong><br />

the highly specific skills that are needed for operation (exemplified by the expertise<br />

needed to operate a nuclear power plant or a mine). We therefore derive two further<br />

propositions:<br />

85


86<br />

Proposition 3<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

<strong>The</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> location-fixity is determined through a firm's dependence on location-<br />

bound resources which are exclusive <strong>and</strong> scarce in supply.<br />

Proposition 4<br />

<strong>The</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> location-fixity is determined through a firm's long-term commitment to<br />

a location with regard to capital <strong>and</strong> assets (sunk costs).<br />

4.5.2 Market-based location-fixity<br />

In pursuance <strong>of</strong> their raison d'être firms are dependent on having access to their<br />

markets. <strong>The</strong> extent, to which geographical proximity to these markets is required,<br />

significantly depends on the firm's products <strong>and</strong> services. More precisely, productrelated<br />

market proximity is determined by the products' nature <strong>and</strong> transportation cost.<br />

For our research object geographical market proximity is not a universal requirement,<br />

as illustrated by the example <strong>of</strong> electricity or gas utilities, whose output can be<br />

efficiently transported over long distances. For such network industries the sole<br />

condition to ensure output distribution is their principal access to the network, as the<br />

medium to their customers. On the other side <strong>of</strong> the market-proximity continuum are<br />

industries whose transportation costs account for a significant fraction <strong>of</strong> the product<br />

price, as exemplified by the cement industry. To remain competitive production sites<br />

need to be located close to the customer base. Consequently, product reach in such<br />

industries is determined by the competitive environment, resulting in a competitive<br />

advantage for the player with relatively smaller transportation cost in areas <strong>of</strong><br />

competitive overlap, <strong>and</strong> by the available transportation modes, such as cost-efficient<br />

shipping in the case <strong>of</strong> cement. Located in between those extremes are the providers <strong>of</strong><br />

public or quasi-public infrastructure, such as railway networks or airports. <strong>The</strong>ir<br />

catchment area is determined by the maximum distance a customer is willing to accept<br />

to reach the infrastructure. As a result <strong>of</strong> these downstream limitations for some UCI,<br />

we further propose:<br />

Proposition 5<br />

<strong>The</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> location-fixity is determined through a need to be geographically close<br />

to the customer, due to the nature <strong>of</strong> the product for some UCF.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

4.5.3 Ownership-based location-fixity<br />

Depending on the industry characteristics <strong>and</strong> on the national industry structure, many<br />

UCF are under total or partial public (i.e. government) ownership. Due to the public<br />

service or public good character <strong>of</strong> the majority <strong>of</strong> UCI, governments frequently see an<br />

advantage in retaining a degree <strong>of</strong> control through financial involvement. As public<br />

shareholders, be it the state, related bodies, or other public institutions <strong>of</strong> regional or<br />

local scale, they follow interests which might deviate from simple pr<strong>of</strong>it-maximisation,<br />

for example by also considering public policy objectives <strong>and</strong> macro-economic<br />

implications (cf. OECD, 2007: 110f). In particular this applies for utilities, whose<br />

strategic importance for the local economy frequently induce public shareholders' to<br />

prioritise price stability <strong>and</strong> security <strong>of</strong> supply before private-sector objectives.<br />

As a consequence the firm's interest to diversify its risks, seek synergies or to exp<strong>and</strong><br />

beyond its home territory may st<strong>and</strong> in conflict with its public owners' agenda. Firms<br />

which are thus limited in their strategic options are characterised by the third type <strong>of</strong><br />

location-fixity, being inhibited in their pr<strong>of</strong>it-seeking <strong>and</strong> operational optimisations<br />

with regard to spatial flexibility.<br />

Proposition 6<br />

<strong>The</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> location-fixity is also determined by the ownership structure <strong>of</strong> the firm,<br />

when the owner pursues public policy objectives, or if his utility function in general<br />

incorporates factors other than pr<strong>of</strong>it-seeking.<br />

4.6 Institutional exposure<br />

From an institutional perspective, concerned with the influences <strong>of</strong> normative<br />

pressures on organisations (Zucker, 1987), the context <strong>and</strong> environment in which a<br />

firm is embedded is <strong>of</strong> central relevance. Various research streams have addressed<br />

context-related topics 27 , strengthening the rationale that organisations' adaptation to the<br />

collective normative order increases the flow <strong>of</strong> societal resources, thus enhancing<br />

“long-run survival prospects” (Meyer & Rowan, 1977: 252). In other words, “the longterm<br />

survival <strong>and</strong> success <strong>of</strong> a firm is determined by its ability to establish <strong>and</strong><br />

maintain relationships within its entire network <strong>of</strong> stakeholders” (Post et al., 2002a: 7).<br />

27 E.g. stakeholder theory <strong>and</strong> research on corporate social responsibility within strategic management,<br />

or research within the relational view <strong>of</strong> institutionalism, economic geography, <strong>and</strong> institutional<br />

economics.<br />

87


88<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

As an open system 28 , the firm constantly receives positive <strong>and</strong> negative external<br />

impulses, to which it is expected to be receptive. Since the firm's activities affect<br />

public interests, while inversely activities in the public interest also affect the firm<br />

(Dyllick, 1992) it is crucial that the firm is aware in which ways it depends on its<br />

stakeholders, respectively how these dependencies could impact its prospects. With<br />

reference to our research object this systemic interconnectedness is particularly<br />

influential: due to the externalities that UCFs usually emit to the local environment,<br />

their related visibility <strong>and</strong> their location-fixity, they highly rely on favourable relations<br />

with their direct <strong>and</strong> indirect stakeholders. This reliance on the institutional<br />

environment is reflected in our research framework through the construct <strong>of</strong><br />

'institutional exposure', understood as an exogenous factor, which the firm takes as<br />

given.<br />

Definition <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure (concise)<br />

<strong>The</strong> degree to which a firm is exposed <strong>and</strong> vulnerable to claims, dem<strong>and</strong>s, <strong>and</strong><br />

expectations <strong>of</strong> its local stakeholders.<br />

An assessment <strong>of</strong> the firm's institutional exposure vis-à-vis its individual stakeholders<br />

can be likened to the creation <strong>of</strong> a risk-map which points out potential negative<br />

impacts the stakeholder could have on the firm <strong>and</strong> its potential for value<br />

appropriation. Before assessing UCFs institutional exposure in more detail by the<br />

individual stakeholders, the next two subchapters provide an introduction into the<br />

concepts <strong>and</strong> theories underlying the notion - drawing on stakeholder theory <strong>and</strong><br />

transaction cost theory - with the objective to substantiate the theoretical grounding <strong>of</strong><br />

the institutional exposure construct.<br />

4.6.1 <strong>The</strong>oretical grounding <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure: stakeholder theory<br />

Stakeholder theory has its roots in the 1950s as a response to activities by large<br />

corporations with potentially severe repercussions on society's welfare. Since then<br />

stakeholder conception has evolved in the course <strong>of</strong> various academic discussions. One<br />

<strong>of</strong> the central notions <strong>of</strong> this wide field <strong>of</strong> research is the acknowledgement <strong>of</strong> a<br />

corporate social responsibility beyond plain pr<strong>of</strong>it generation, as initially suggested by<br />

Friedman (1962), <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> the necessity to integrate business in society, wherein society<br />

lends legitimacy <strong>and</strong> prestige to the business (Garriga & Melé, 2004).<br />

28 See also Ack<strong>of</strong>f (1974), who pioneered the 'open systems' approach within system theory.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Defining stakeholders. <strong>The</strong> term 'stakeholder' was originally coined in an internal<br />

memo at the Stanford Research Institute (SRI) in 1963, defining them as “those groups<br />

without whose support the organisation would cease to exist” (SRI, 1963, as cited in<br />

Freeman & Reed, 1983: 89). In this early definition the relations between the firm <strong>and</strong><br />

its stakeholders were seen as non-adversarial, with the exception <strong>of</strong> labourmanagement<br />

relations. This notion was challenged by Dill's (1975: 58) definition <strong>of</strong><br />

stakeholders as “people outside ... who have ideas about what the economic <strong>and</strong> social<br />

performance <strong>of</strong> the enterprise should include”. In his argumentation towards better<br />

integrating stakeholder considerations in firms' strategic decisions, he leveraged the<br />

stakeholder concept to become a central determinant <strong>of</strong> strategic management<br />

research. With an emphasis on the reciprocal influence between firms <strong>and</strong><br />

stakeholders, Freeman <strong>and</strong> Reed (1983: 91) extended the conception by defining<br />

stakeholders as “any identifiable group or individual who can affect the achievement<br />

<strong>of</strong> an organisation's objectives or who is affected by the achievement <strong>of</strong> an<br />

organisation's objectives”. Consequently, the rights <strong>and</strong> interests a stakeholder claims<br />

or has in a firm <strong>and</strong> its activities result from transactions with, or actions taken by the<br />

firm (Clarkson, 1995), as well as from the stakeholder's 'threat potential', i.e. the<br />

degree to which he may affect the achievement <strong>of</strong> the firm's objectives. This notion<br />

links the stakeholder concept with our institutional exposure construct, commending<br />

adequate stakeholder management as a response towards reducing the firm's exposure.<br />

As illustrated in this brief overview, various approaches may be taken towards the<br />

conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> stakeholders within stakeholder theory. As a result, there is still<br />

theoretical discord in respect <strong>of</strong> distinguishing those individuals <strong>and</strong> groups that are<br />

stakeholders from those that are not (Phillips & Reichart, 2000). <strong>The</strong> next section<br />

reviews a number <strong>of</strong> stakeholder classification schemes <strong>and</strong> approaches towards<br />

stakeholder identification.<br />

Stakeholder identification. One <strong>of</strong> the difficulties in mapping the firm's stakeholders<br />

derives from the fact that these include individuals, groups <strong>and</strong> organisations, each <strong>of</strong><br />

which st<strong>and</strong>ing in a specific relationship to the firm, while their composition <strong>and</strong><br />

membership keeps changing. All the more, a sensible stakeholder grouping is essential<br />

to the firm in order to remain focused <strong>and</strong> to reduce complexity in the management <strong>of</strong><br />

stakeholder relations. <strong>The</strong> observation, that the spectrum <strong>of</strong> active stakeholders tends<br />

to increase with a firm's degree <strong>of</strong> public exposure (Achleitner, 1985) adds additional<br />

importance with hindsight to our research object. Stakeholder research has brought<br />

forward a number <strong>of</strong> stakeholder classification schemes, the most important <strong>of</strong> which<br />

89


90<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

are briefly described below 29 . With this review we intend to increase clarity on who<br />

should be regarded as a legitimate stakeholder, <strong>and</strong> after which criteria we should draw<br />

the line <strong>of</strong> exclusion within our research framework.<br />

Internal <strong>and</strong> external stakeholders. Certainly the most widely used classification<br />

distinguishes between internal <strong>and</strong> external stakeholders. While the internal<br />

stakeholders are rather given, including shareholders, the management, <strong>and</strong><br />

employees, the external stakeholders comprise lenders <strong>of</strong> capital, suppliers, customers,<br />

the government <strong>and</strong> society, <strong>and</strong> potentially further groups.<br />

Internal<br />

stakeholders<br />

employees<br />

managers<br />

shareholders<br />

firm<br />

External<br />

stakeholders<br />

suppliers<br />

society<br />

government<br />

creditors<br />

customers<br />

Figure 4-5: Internal <strong>and</strong> external stakeholder classification 30<br />

…<br />

Primary <strong>and</strong> secondary stakeholders. Depending on a stakeholder's role <strong>and</strong><br />

importance for the firm's going concern, Clarkson (1995) distinguishes between<br />

primary <strong>and</strong> secondary stakeholders. <strong>The</strong> relationship between primary stakeholder<br />

groups <strong>and</strong> the firm is characterised by high levels <strong>of</strong> interaction, with the continuous<br />

stakeholder participation being critical for the firm's going concern. Such primary<br />

stakeholders are shareholders <strong>and</strong> investors, employees, customers, suppliers, <strong>and</strong><br />

public stakeholders, such as governments <strong>and</strong> communities. Apart from those closely<br />

related stakeholders, secondary stakeholder groups influence or affect, or are<br />

influenced or affected by the firm. Although they are not engaged in transactions with<br />

the corporation <strong>and</strong> are not essential for its survival, they are capable <strong>of</strong> mobilising<br />

public opinion, thus impacting a firm's performance. <strong>The</strong> media <strong>and</strong> special interest<br />

groups for example are attributed to this category.<br />

29 An excellent <strong>and</strong> more detailed overview on existing classifications can be found in Helm (2007), as<br />

well as in Donaldson & Preston (1995).<br />

30<br />

On the basis <strong>of</strong> Mintzberg (1983).


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Power-centred identification. Stakeholder power <strong>and</strong> influence represent another<br />

widely used set <strong>of</strong> criteria for stakeholder mapping. In the course <strong>of</strong> the past decades a<br />

“consciousness [evolved] among stakeholders <strong>of</strong> the fragility <strong>of</strong> world social systems,<br />

<strong>of</strong> global resource limits, <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> unanticipated outcomes <strong>of</strong> both private <strong>and</strong> public<br />

action” (Dill, 1975: 58). <strong>The</strong>refore, as Dill (ibid.) was the first to observe, stakeholders<br />

not only contribute to the economic success <strong>of</strong> a firm, but also have an inherent threat<br />

potential. This potential represents the dependence <strong>of</strong> the firm on the respective<br />

stakeholder, i.e. the firm's capability to withdraw from the raised claims by<br />

substituting the relationship. In line with the RBV, stakeholder dependence represents<br />

a form <strong>of</strong> resource-dependence (Eberhardt, 1998), further determined by the<br />

stakeholder's capability to realise the formulated threats. This threat immanence<br />

represents the actual imperilment <strong>of</strong> the firm (Helm, 2007).<br />

Stakeholders as risk-bearers. Clarkson (1994) partitions stakeholders subject to their<br />

being voluntary or involuntary risk-bearers. In his view (ibid., as cited in Mitchell et<br />

al., 1997: 856f.)<br />

voluntary stakeholders bear some form <strong>of</strong> risk as a result <strong>of</strong> having invested some<br />

form <strong>of</strong> capital, human or financial, something <strong>of</strong> value, in a firm. Involuntary<br />

stakeholders are placed at risk as a result <strong>of</strong> a firm's activities. But without the<br />

element <strong>of</strong> risk there is no stake.<br />

By determining risk as the discriminating factor for having a stake in the firm narrows<br />

the range <strong>of</strong> stakeholders down <strong>and</strong> closely corresponds with the legitimate claims<br />

classification.<br />

Legitimacy-based identification. Stakeholder legitimacy research argues from a<br />

normative viewpoint, focusing on contracts, formal exchanges, legal titles <strong>and</strong> rights,<br />

moral rights, or moral interest in the positive or negative externalities induced by the<br />

firm's actions. In exp<strong>and</strong>ing this perspective, Phillips (2003) argues that legitimacy can<br />

be normative, based on moral obligations towards stakeholders, but that it also may be<br />

<strong>of</strong> derivative nature, referring to “those groups whose actions <strong>and</strong> claims must be<br />

accounted for by managers due to their potential effects upon the organisation <strong>and</strong> its<br />

normative stakeholders” (ibid: 31). <strong>The</strong> approach allows for an integration <strong>of</strong> moral<br />

philosophical streams <strong>and</strong> the more strategic conceptions towards stakeholder<br />

management.<br />

Combined approaches towards stakeholder identification. In their research on<br />

stakeholder salience Mitchell, Agle <strong>and</strong> Wood (1997) observed that scientific<br />

contributions with a narrow stakeholder definition emphasise the legitimacy aspect <strong>of</strong><br />

91


92<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

stakeholder claims. In contrast, researchers favouring a broad stakeholder definition<br />

emphasise the aspect <strong>of</strong> stakeholder power towards the firm, irrespective <strong>of</strong> their<br />

claims' legitimacy. In an attempt to bridge these two extremes <strong>of</strong> stakeholder<br />

conceptualisations, they propose to combine the notions <strong>of</strong> stakeholder power <strong>and</strong><br />

stakeholder legitimacy - which may coincide, but are distinct attributes 31 - with the<br />

urgency <strong>of</strong> a claim. Urgency, as the “degree to which stakeholder claims call for<br />

immediate attention” (ibid.: 864), is derived from institutional, resource dependence,<br />

<strong>and</strong> population ecology theories' concern with outside pressures on the firm. In this<br />

combined approach stakeholder salience thus relates to the cumulative occurrence <strong>of</strong><br />

all three attributes.<br />

An alternative view is <strong>of</strong>fered by Phillips (2003), who principally agrees on these three<br />

suggested attributes but sees legitimacy as a superordinated attribute, <strong>of</strong> which<br />

stakeholder power is but one possible substantiation. In his view, managers' attention<br />

should be directed to stakeholders according to their normative <strong>and</strong> derived legitimacy,<br />

a distinction which “brings together both moral philosophical <strong>and</strong> strategic<br />

conceptions <strong>of</strong> stakeholder theory <strong>and</strong> thereby integrates these two <strong>of</strong>ten oppositional<br />

streams <strong>of</strong> stakeholder research” (ibid.: 29). Normative stakeholders are identified as<br />

those, for whose benefit the firm should be managed (Freeman, 1984; Phillips, 2003).<br />

<strong>The</strong>y require particular managerial attention <strong>and</strong> treatment, since managers have<br />

distinct ethical obligations towards them. <strong>The</strong>se obligations do not necessarily exist<br />

towards derivative stakeholders, defined as “those groups whose actions <strong>and</strong> claims<br />

must be accounted for by managers due to their potential effects upon the organisation<br />

<strong>and</strong> its normative stakeholders” (Phillips, 2003: 31). <strong>The</strong> significance <strong>of</strong> the normative<br />

- derivative distinction becomes evident in the example <strong>of</strong> a firm's competition. While<br />

a competitor doubtlessly qualifies as a derivative stakeholder, since its activities affect<br />

the firm <strong>and</strong> it thus possesses stakeholder power, it is certainly not a stakeholder for<br />

whose benefit the firm should be managed. Phillip's (ibid.) distinction between the<br />

morally-grounded legitimacy <strong>and</strong> other considerations is beneficial in the firm's<br />

prioritising <strong>of</strong> stakeholder dem<strong>and</strong>s: managers have a primary obligation towards<br />

normative stakeholders, while attention to derivative stakeholder dem<strong>and</strong>s comes<br />

logically second.<br />

Building on these bridging concepts, Kochan <strong>and</strong> Rubinstein (2000) suggest to assess<br />

stakeholder salience along three criteria: (1) stakeholders' control over critical<br />

resources (i.e. the contribution <strong>of</strong> critical resources or assets to the firm), (2)<br />

31 See also Weber (1947).


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

stakeholders' risks pertaining to the firm (i.e. the extent to which they put resources at<br />

risk <strong>and</strong> would incur costs if the firm fails or the relationship with the firm terminates),<br />

<strong>and</strong> (3) stakeholders' power <strong>and</strong> influence on the firm (i.e. their capacity to affect firm<br />

performance, either favourably or unfavourably). <strong>The</strong> second criterion endows<br />

stakeholders with normative legitimacy, whereas the other two criteria warrant them<br />

with derived legitimacy. In line with the contextual approach <strong>of</strong> our framework, the<br />

resources featured in the first criterion are understood to also include intangibles, such<br />

as social acceptance or the “license to operate”, which are equally critical for the firm's<br />

long-term prospects. Likewise the stakeholder risks in criterion (2) are viewed<br />

comprehensively <strong>and</strong> encompass risks with regard to the stakeholder's financial<br />

resources, human resources, but also his risks related to the firm's product quality (e.g.<br />

for a supplier's reputation), or the firm's effects on its environment <strong>and</strong> local<br />

community (cf. Post et al., 2002b) (e.g. the regional economic effects if a firm<br />

discontinues its local operation).<br />

After reviewing various scientific approaches towards stakeholder identification, we<br />

regard Phillips' (ibid.) conception as the most suitable basis for our research<br />

framework, particularly due to his disentanglement <strong>of</strong> the moral <strong>and</strong> strategic<br />

dimension <strong>of</strong> legitimacy. In the identification <strong>of</strong> relevant stakeholders within our<br />

research framework we will draw on his argumentation <strong>and</strong> on the detailing criteria<br />

<strong>of</strong>fered by Kochan <strong>and</strong> Rubinstein (2000).<br />

4.6.2 Legitimate stakeholders within the research framework<br />

To determine who is a legitimate stakeholder, we firstly highlight the particular<br />

characteristics <strong>of</strong> our research object, which cause an elevated level <strong>of</strong> overall<br />

institutional exposure. Table 4-3 provides an overview on these characteristics, as well<br />

as the stakeholders towards which the firm faces exposure.<br />

93


94<br />

UCF<br />

characteristic<br />

output <strong>of</strong> national<br />

strategic<br />

importance<br />

negative<br />

externalities<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

description exposure towards<br />

UCF usually produce goods or services central<br />

for the functioning <strong>of</strong> the economy or society<br />

(provision <strong>of</strong> electricity, drinking water,<br />

transportation infrastructure, etc.)<br />

output is linked with noise or other kind <strong>of</strong><br />

emissions, potentially hazardous to the environment<br />

<strong>and</strong> lowering the (perceived) welfare <strong>of</strong> the<br />

surrounding population<br />

natural monopoly industry structure that turn UCF quasi-monopolists,<br />

endowing them with market power<br />

dense regulation as a consequence <strong>of</strong> the preceding characteristics,<br />

UCF are under regulatory scrutiny from the relevant<br />

authorities<br />

Table 4-3: UCF characteristics fostering institutional exposure<br />

political actors<br />

public<br />

administration<br />

regulator<br />

general public<br />

political actors<br />

regulator<br />

local community<br />

general public<br />

political actors<br />

regulator<br />

political actors<br />

regulator<br />

In view <strong>of</strong> the combination <strong>of</strong> those characteristics, we draw two inferences: (1) UCFs<br />

are very visible to the public in everything they do, which significantly contributes to<br />

their vulnerability <strong>and</strong> exposure. As a consequence, they face dem<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong><br />

expectations from a wide range <strong>of</strong> stakeholders (cf. Achleitner, 1985). (2) <strong>The</strong><br />

relevance <strong>of</strong> public or sovereign stakeholders to UCFs is significant. Because their<br />

output in some aspects resembles public goods, <strong>and</strong> because <strong>of</strong> their enabling function<br />

for the economy they are under scrutiny <strong>of</strong> various representatives <strong>of</strong> the sovereign,<br />

who want to ensure optimal public policy outcomes. Both insights will be reflected in<br />

the ensuing stakeholder identification.<br />

Geographical delimitation <strong>of</strong> stakeholders. An important delimitation <strong>of</strong> the firm's<br />

relevant stakeholders results from the scope <strong>of</strong> our research framework. <strong>The</strong><br />

geographical dimension <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> the notion <strong>of</strong> local embeddedness,<br />

which will be developed at a later point, require a decidedly local, respectively<br />

regional perspective. Although the geographical range <strong>of</strong> a firm's stakeholders has<br />

increased in the past quarter <strong>of</strong> a century because <strong>of</strong> globalisation, we retain our local<br />

focus by excluding stakeholders which have no relation to the firm's local<br />

environment. This does not preclude differences between stakeholders with regard to<br />

their geographical scales, exemplified by the different geographical scales <strong>of</strong>


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

authorities <strong>and</strong> public administrations, depending on their institutional set-up <strong>and</strong><br />

jurisdiction.<br />

Determining the relevant stakeholders. Based on the above insights into stakeholder<br />

theory, the characteristics <strong>of</strong> our research object, <strong>and</strong> the geographical scope <strong>of</strong> the<br />

research framework, we are now able to determine the relevant stakeholders. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

will be segregated in the two principal groups <strong>of</strong> private <strong>and</strong> public stakeholders,<br />

owing to the high relevance <strong>of</strong> those stakeholders in representation <strong>of</strong> or related to the<br />

sovereign. With reference to the concepts <strong>of</strong> Phillips' (2003) <strong>and</strong> Kochan & Rubinstein<br />

(2000), Table 4-4 identifies the salient <strong>and</strong> legitimate stakeholders within the<br />

geographical scope <strong>of</strong> the research framework.<br />

95


96<br />

private stakeholders<br />

public stakeholders<br />

stakeholder legitimacy (1) control over<br />

resources<br />

civil society<br />

<strong>and</strong> local<br />

community<br />

civilian<br />

interest<br />

groups<br />

normative �<br />

e.g. 'licence to operate'<br />

derivative �<br />

e.g. 'licence to operate'<br />

suppliers normative �<br />

e.g. critical inputs<br />

customers normative �<br />

e.g. reputation<br />

service<br />

partners<br />

normative �<br />

e.g. provision <strong>of</strong> inputs<br />

relevant to the overall<br />

system<br />

employees normative �<br />

e.g. human resources,<br />

skills <strong>and</strong> know-how<br />

public<br />

shareholder<br />

government<br />

(political<br />

dimension)<br />

regulator<br />

(law <strong>and</strong><br />

order<br />

dimension)<br />

normative �<br />

e.g. public policy<br />

support<br />

derivative �<br />

e.g. public policy<br />

support<br />

derivative �<br />

e.g. licences,<br />

concessions,<br />

regulatory approvals<br />

Table 4-4: Legitimate stakeholder groups pertaining to UCFs<br />

Assessment <strong>of</strong> stakeholder salience<br />

(2) stakeh. risks<br />

towards firm<br />

�<br />

e.g. environmental <strong>and</strong><br />

economic risks<br />

�<br />

e.g. financial risks<br />

�<br />

e.g. product-related<br />

risks<br />

�<br />

e.g. dependence on<br />

mutual provision <strong>of</strong><br />

input for functioning<br />

<strong>of</strong> overall system<br />

�<br />

e.g. financial risks,<br />

risks regarding<br />

livelihood<br />

�<br />

e.g. financial risks,<br />

risk <strong>of</strong> public policy<br />

misalignment<br />

�<br />

e.g. re-election <strong>of</strong><br />

political government<br />

representatives<br />

�<br />

e.g. failure to protect<br />

the public good,<br />

factual consequences<br />

<strong>of</strong> firm's noncompliance<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

(3) power <strong>and</strong><br />

influence<br />

�<br />

e.g. withdrawal <strong>of</strong><br />

support<br />

�<br />

e.g. active lobbying<br />

against the interests <strong>of</strong><br />

the firm; potential to<br />

mobilise other<br />

stakeholders<br />

�<br />

e.g. withdrawal <strong>of</strong><br />

resource; influence on<br />

product quality<br />

�<br />

e.g. withdrawal <strong>of</strong><br />

support <strong>and</strong><br />

termination <strong>of</strong><br />

customer-relation<br />

�<br />

e.g. termination <strong>of</strong><br />

input-provision,<br />

disrupting the overall<br />

system<br />

�<br />

e.g. withdrawal <strong>of</strong><br />

resource or support<br />

�<br />

e.g. withdrawal <strong>of</strong><br />

support, obstruction to<br />

business development<br />

�<br />

e.g. withdrawal <strong>of</strong><br />

support, active<br />

lobbying against the<br />

interests <strong>of</strong> the firm<br />

�<br />

e.g. denial <strong>of</strong><br />

regulatory approval,<br />

penalties, additional<br />

conditions to operation


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Figure 4-6 illustrates the two stakeholder categories as part <strong>of</strong> the institutional<br />

exposure construct, <strong>and</strong> how they relate to the overall research framework.<br />

local exposure from<br />

moderate<br />

location fixity (4.5 - 4.7) value creation (4.9)<br />

influences<br />

location fixity (4.5)<br />

constitutes<br />

institutional exposure (4.6)<br />

private stakeholders<br />

local community<br />

interest groups<br />

customers<br />

suppliers<br />

service partners<br />

employees (unions)<br />

public stakeholders<br />

public shareholder<br />

government<br />

regulator<br />

embedding<br />

capabilities (4.8)<br />

Figure 4-6: Institutional exposure <strong>and</strong> stakeholder groups within the research framework<br />

Before immersing more deeply in the analysis <strong>of</strong> UCFs' institutional exposure towards<br />

their legitimate stakeholders, we briefly introduce the core notions <strong>of</strong> transaction cost<br />

theory with the objective to theoretically ground our assumptions on human behaviour<br />

<strong>and</strong> the potential effects <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure on the firm.<br />

4.6.3 <strong>The</strong>oretical grounding <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure: transaction cost theory<br />

As stipulated by a number <strong>of</strong> organisational theories, power accrues to those who<br />

control resources needed by the organisation (e.g. Pfeffer, 1981). In their endeavours<br />

to secure the resources required for survival <strong>and</strong> prosperity, firms consequently seek<br />

strategies to reduce their dependence on resources beyond their sphere <strong>of</strong> control, or at<br />

least to mitigate the thereto related risks. Such power differentials <strong>and</strong> the mechanisms<br />

to govern them are among the subjects <strong>of</strong> transaction cost economics (TCE), which is<br />

“an effort to identify, explicate, <strong>and</strong> mitigate contractual hazards” (OE Williamson,<br />

1996: 12). Pivotal to its concepts are its assumptions on the human nature, which it<br />

owes to organisation theory. According to TCE human behaviour is assumed to be<br />

governed by the notions <strong>of</strong> opportunism, understood as “self-interest seeking with<br />

guile” (OE Williamson, 1996: 6), <strong>and</strong> bounded rationality, defined as behaviour that is<br />

97


98<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

“intendedly rational, but only limitedly so [emphasis in original]” (Simon, 1961: xxiv),<br />

both <strong>of</strong> which will be further described in the ensuing passages.<br />

Opportunism. Opportunism can take many forms, which research has tried to classify<br />

from different angles. Most common is the distinction between passive <strong>and</strong> active (i.e.<br />

strong form) types <strong>of</strong> opportunism. In its passive form opportunism manifests itself in<br />

the lack <strong>of</strong> dedication, shirking or free-riding, while the active form relates to the<br />

expropriation <strong>of</strong> advantage through deliberate misrepresentation <strong>of</strong> material facts,<br />

cheating, lying, stealing, etc. (Nooteboom, 2004). On a temporal dimension, either<br />

party in an exchange can engage in opportunism before the firms transact (i.e. ex ante<br />

opportunism), or after the transaction is underway (i.e. ex post opportunism). Last but<br />

not least, on the legal dimension research distinguishes a 'lawful opportunism',<br />

describing opportunistic behaviour which does not breach the formal contract, but<br />

violates the relational contract between the parties (Wathne & Heide, 2000). In this<br />

enlarged conception behaviour is also opportunistic, if it is contrary to the principles <strong>of</strong><br />

the relation in which it occurs. Such relational norms include the expectation <strong>of</strong><br />

sharing benefits <strong>and</strong> burdens, as well as restraints on unilateral use <strong>of</strong> power (Macneil,<br />

1980). Importantly, in addition to these intentional forms <strong>of</strong> opportunism, also honest<br />

disagreements that result in distributional <strong>and</strong> costly conflicts, may contain<br />

opportunistic elements (Alchian & Woodward, 1988).<br />

In his early conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> opportunism 32 Williamson (1985a: 181) describes the<br />

behaviour as incomplete or distorted disclosure <strong>of</strong> information <strong>and</strong> “calculated efforts<br />

to mislead, distort, disguise, obfuscate, or otherwise confuse”. This strong form <strong>of</strong><br />

opportunism was seen as a fixed exogenous condition, assuming that all potential<br />

transaction partners are equally weakly moral. Later research has led to an<br />

enhancement <strong>of</strong> the concept, rather viewing opportunism as a variable to be explained<br />

(Wathne & Heide, 2000). Throughout chapter 4 we will repeatedly return to the notion<br />

<strong>of</strong> opportunism <strong>and</strong> related concepts.<br />

Bounded rationality. <strong>The</strong> concept <strong>of</strong> bounded rationality rests upon the premise that<br />

the rationality <strong>of</strong> human beings is limited by their available information, their<br />

cognitive limitations, <strong>and</strong> the finite amount <strong>of</strong> time they have to make decisions. It is<br />

the key to underst<strong>and</strong>ing how people make decisions without utilities <strong>and</strong> probabilities<br />

<strong>and</strong> leads to the empirically confirmed insight, that “decision makers satisfice instead<br />

<strong>of</strong> optimise, rarely engage in comprehensive search, <strong>and</strong> discover their goals in the<br />

32 <strong>The</strong> concept <strong>of</strong> opportunism originates from transaction cost theory, but is also implicitly assumed<br />

within the RBV. For further discussion <strong>of</strong> opportunism within the RBV see also Mahoney (2001).


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

process <strong>of</strong> searching” (Eisenhardt & Zbaracki, 1992). Firms' decisions therefore are<br />

not expected to be perfect, since their decision processes are influenced by institutional<br />

factors, leading to boundedly rational outcomes.<br />

Reference to research object. Under condition <strong>of</strong> bounded rationality <strong>and</strong> with our<br />

research object's characteristics pertaining to location-fixity, stakeholders <strong>of</strong> the UCF<br />

may be apt to opportunistic behaviour <strong>and</strong> attempts to expropriate some <strong>of</strong> the firm's<br />

rent. This notion is supported by the close theoretical relation between the concepts <strong>of</strong><br />

asset specificity <strong>and</strong> opportunism (Pies, 2001). According to TCE firms become<br />

increasingly prone to opportunistic behaviour from their stakeholders as their assetspecificity<br />

deepens, or as Klein, Crawford <strong>and</strong> Alchian specify: “after a specific<br />

investment is made <strong>and</strong> … quasi rents 33 are created, the possibility <strong>of</strong> opportunistic<br />

behaviour is very real” (1978: 298). In other words asset specificity becomes a<br />

problem for firms because <strong>of</strong> opportunism. As a consequence, UCFs have to find<br />

strategies to avoid rent appropriation, respectively to reduce their institutional<br />

exposure towards stakeholders who could cause opportunistic hold-up situations.<br />

Building on the first, simplified definition <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure, the foregoing<br />

theoretical insights lead us to a more detailed specification.<br />

Definition <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure (extended):<br />

<strong>The</strong> degree to which a firm is prone to negative effects on its value creation capacity<br />

<strong>and</strong> to rent appropriation by opportunistic stakeholders, due to its inability to substitute<br />

the relationship or location.<br />

4.6.4 Institutional exposure by identified stakeholder groups<br />

Now that the theoretical foundation for the institutional exposure construct is<br />

established, <strong>and</strong> the legitimate stakeholders are identified within our research object,<br />

we continue with the detailing <strong>of</strong> UCFs' institutional exposure towards the individual<br />

stakeholder groups.<br />

<strong>Local</strong> Community (as a spatially bounded part <strong>of</strong> civil society). (1) Definitional<br />

clarification. Within the social sciences civil society represents the community “in a<br />

social space related to, but distinguished from, government, business <strong>and</strong> the private<br />

sphere” (Kocka, 2006: vii). Furthermore, it “refers to the arena <strong>of</strong> uncoerced collective<br />

33 Quasi-rents are defined as the income earned by a sunk cost investment in excess <strong>of</strong> post-investment<br />

opportunity cost. To ascertain their long-term prosperity, UCFs need them to recover their sunk costs.<br />

99


100<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

action around shared interests, purposes <strong>and</strong> values” (LSE Centre for Civil Society,<br />

2004). Society is socially <strong>and</strong> geographically delimited <strong>and</strong> shares interests, purposes<br />

<strong>and</strong> values, without being essentially united. To be distinguished there<strong>of</strong>, communities<br />

are a tighter <strong>and</strong> more cohesive social entity, either in space, or through interaction,<br />

respectively identity (Lee & Newby, 1983; Tönnies, [1887] 2001). <strong>The</strong> geographical<br />

characterisation, relevant within our research framework, represents people residing<br />

within the same geographic region, not necessarily interacting among them 34 . This<br />

lack <strong>of</strong> 'unity <strong>of</strong> will' (Tönnies, [1887] 2001) <strong>and</strong> interaction poses considerable<br />

challenges in addressing the local community as a stakeholder, due to its highly<br />

diverse interests, claims, <strong>and</strong> expectations (Kocka, 2006).<br />

(2) Relation to research framework. <strong>Local</strong> communities with regard to UCFs are<br />

bounded by the reach <strong>of</strong> the firm's externalities within its local environment,<br />

respectively by the jurisdiction towards which they administratively related to, e.g. the<br />

local municipality or district. <strong>The</strong>y draw their (normative) legitimacy from their<br />

exposure to these externalities, which affect the welfare <strong>of</strong> the community members,<br />

who put values or properties at risk <strong>and</strong> therefore derive a stake in the firm.<br />

Externalities are understood as positive (e.g. employment opportunities, tax revenues<br />

being re-invested in local institutions <strong>and</strong> infrastructure, attraction <strong>of</strong> further<br />

industries) or negative (e.g. emissions in the form <strong>of</strong> air <strong>and</strong> water pollution, or noise)<br />

spillovers.<br />

(3) Related institutional exposure. <strong>The</strong> degree to which the UCF is institutionally<br />

exposed to its local community is a function <strong>of</strong> the community's willingness to accept<br />

the welfare effects <strong>of</strong> the negative externalities, respectively to value them against the<br />

perceived compensation that the firm <strong>of</strong>fers. Such compensation may be in the form <strong>of</strong><br />

positive externalities, community engagement programmes, investment in social<br />

infrastructure, etc. (see also p.133ff.). Thus, there is a kind <strong>of</strong> 'societal regulation' for<br />

firms, outside the political sphere in the form <strong>of</strong> 'subpolitical norms' (Dyllick, 2001).<br />

<strong>The</strong> overall perception <strong>of</strong> the firm's stakeholder involvement <strong>and</strong> willingness to share<br />

value as a compensatory effort towards the community helps the firm to gain a 'license<br />

to operate'. If the negative effects <strong>of</strong> the firm's activities prevail in the local<br />

community's perception, it might resort to uncoerced collective action, using<br />

34 By contrast, interaction-based communities are not necessarily place-based, <strong>and</strong> identity-based<br />

communities represent "a group who share a sense <strong>of</strong> belonging, generally built upon a shared set <strong>of</strong><br />

beliefs, values or experiences" (Bowen, Newenham-Kahindi, & Herremans, 2008: 10).


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

reputation-impairing pressure potentials ('reputationsschädigende Druckpotentiale', in<br />

accordance with Dyllick, 2001).<br />

Civilian interest groups. (1) Definitional clarification. Generally interest groups<br />

“share a desire to affect government policy to benefit themselves or their cause. It<br />

could be a policy that exclusively benefits group members or one segment <strong>of</strong> society<br />

… or a policy that advances a broader public purpose” 35 . In contrast to the local<br />

community, which is only loosely bounded, interest groups usually are formally<br />

organised. <strong>The</strong>y exist in various forms, with economic or civilian objectives, political<br />

or non-political orientation, or memberships for individuals or organisations.<br />

(2) Relation to research framework. Within our framework, interest groups are<br />

understood as civilian or public interest groups, promoting issues <strong>of</strong> general public<br />

concern, <strong>and</strong> as cause groups, which represent a segment <strong>of</strong> society <strong>and</strong> promote a<br />

particular cause. As opposed to political <strong>and</strong> economic interest groups, respectively<br />

lobbies, their efforts are not directed at economic gain or influencing the political<br />

agenda. <strong>The</strong> political arena will only be entered, if there is no other perceived way <strong>of</strong><br />

protecting their interests.<br />

(3) Related institutional exposure. <strong>The</strong> institutional exposure <strong>of</strong> the UCF towards<br />

interest groups bases on their capacity to use reputation-impairing pressure potentials<br />

(Dyllick, 2001), their potential to mobilise other stakeholder groups (in particular<br />

public stakeholders, such as policy-makers <strong>and</strong> regulators), <strong>and</strong> their overall capacity<br />

to affect the firm's value creation, respectively to destroy value for the firm.<br />

Customers <strong>and</strong> Suppliers. (1) Definitional clarification. Customers <strong>and</strong> suppliers are<br />

the key stakeholders <strong>of</strong> any firm. <strong>The</strong> relevance <strong>and</strong> number <strong>of</strong> individual customers,<br />

understood as end consumers or in business to business relations, depend on the firm's<br />

industry <strong>and</strong> its products, as well as its size <strong>and</strong> organisation. Accordingly the firm's<br />

stakeholder strategy towards its customers varies. Suppliers may be providers <strong>of</strong><br />

tangible or intangible inputs to the firm. <strong>The</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> a supplier predominantly<br />

depends on the input's relevance in the firm's production process, <strong>and</strong> the degree to<br />

which the input is a commodity <strong>and</strong> the supplier could be exchanged.<br />

(2) Relation to research framework. <strong>The</strong> normative legitimacy <strong>of</strong> both stakeholders<br />

bases on all three dimensions <strong>of</strong> stakeholder salience, since their relationship with the<br />

firm involves control over resources, risks, <strong>and</strong> endow them with a degree <strong>of</strong> power<br />

35 Interest group. (2009). In Encyclopædia Britannica. Retrieved October 23, 2009, from<br />

Encyclopædia Britannica Online: http://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/290136/interest-group.<br />

101


102<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

<strong>and</strong> influence (cf. Table 4-4, p.96). Due to the location-fixity <strong>and</strong> the local resource<br />

dependence <strong>of</strong> the UCF, particularly suppliers with control over critical local resources<br />

have a high legitimacy, not only from a normative point <strong>of</strong> view, but also pertaining to<br />

strategic considerations.<br />

(3) Related institutional exposure. <strong>The</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> UCFs products, the complexity <strong>of</strong><br />

their industries, <strong>and</strong> the fact that they are tied to their location over a long time<br />

horizon, all encourage stable <strong>and</strong> enduring customer <strong>and</strong> supplier relationships.<br />

Frequently these are accompanied by (mutual) dependence <strong>and</strong> exposure, which TCE<br />

attributes to four elements: the degree <strong>of</strong> asset specificity, uncertainty, product<br />

complexity, <strong>and</strong> the constraints <strong>of</strong> repeat purchase activity (Joskow, 1988). Among the<br />

key challenges to reduce such dependence by means <strong>of</strong> contracts <strong>and</strong> formal<br />

governance system is the problem <strong>of</strong> incomplete contracting. Although relationships<br />

with long-term suppliers or customers usually are governed by more or less<br />

comprehensive contracts, these may turn out incomplete over time, because they are<br />

maladaptive to unforeseen contingencies, <strong>and</strong> because the contract parties over time<br />

gain deeper knowledge compared to the outset <strong>of</strong> the contract (OE Williamson, 1983,<br />

1991). <strong>The</strong>refore frequently hold-up or opportunism problems must be confronted by<br />

the transacting parties at the contract execution stage (Joskow, 1988). Moreover, legal<br />

rule can only incompletely accommodate the complexities <strong>of</strong> the parties' relations,<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten resulting in the use <strong>of</strong> private ordering solutions to the specific situation, in order<br />

to enhance transactional security <strong>and</strong> to reduce transaction costs. Consequently, UCFs<br />

face not only a contractual but also a relational exposure in their customer or supplier<br />

relations (<strong>and</strong> vice versa) for which they must find protective governance structures to<br />

avoid post-contractual opportunistic behaviour.<br />

Service Partners. (1) Definitional clarification. Service partners are actors who<br />

contribute complementarily to an overall product, as for example in an in-depth<br />

customer-supplier relationship based on the partners' strategic status <strong>and</strong> mutual<br />

dependence. Service partnerships are characterised by the partners' joint <strong>of</strong>fering <strong>of</strong><br />

independent services, which contribute to a comprehensive overall solution for the<br />

customer. In this process the service partners may also jointly use a common resource.<br />

<strong>The</strong> customer usually is able to differentiate between the various contributors, but<br />

links the services towards one perceived overall product (Benkenstein, 1996;<br />

Birkelbach, 1993).<br />

(2) Relation to research framework. <strong>The</strong> complexity <strong>of</strong> UCFs' products frequently<br />

leads to service partnerships, wherein a number <strong>of</strong> partners jointly contribute to the


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

overall product <strong>of</strong>fering. <strong>The</strong> dependence on a service partner, <strong>and</strong> thus the firm's<br />

exposure, is determined by the degree to which the services in question require special<br />

know-how <strong>and</strong> to which degree such know-how is found in the market. <strong>The</strong> regulatory<br />

frameworks within UCF are embedded <strong>and</strong> the expertise that their industries require<br />

may make it difficult to exchange service partners. A typical example for service<br />

partnerships is found at airports, whose business models frequently foresee service<br />

delivery in aircraft <strong>and</strong> passenger-related processes through a number <strong>of</strong> well attuned<br />

third parties.<br />

(3) Related institutional exposure. Service partnerships, which are characterised by<br />

their mutuality, intensity, frequency <strong>and</strong> mid- to long-term orientation, may encourage<br />

hold-up situations particularly in dynamically changing business environments with<br />

shifting balances in bargaining power. <strong>The</strong> UCF's institutional exposure principally<br />

pertains to the same factors as in its supplier <strong>and</strong> customer relations: while the<br />

relationships are structured in contracts (<strong>of</strong>ten accompanied by service level<br />

agreements), the latter may be incomplete or become maladaptive due to unexpected<br />

changes over time.<br />

Employees. (1) Definitional clarification. Employees belong to the firm's primary<br />

stakeholders. <strong>The</strong> more specialised a business is, the more important its employees are<br />

as a resource, embodying their practical knowledge, acquired skills <strong>and</strong> learned<br />

abilities.<br />

(2) Relation to research framework. <strong>The</strong>ir normative legitimacy derives, among<br />

others, from their investments in the firm, respectively in firm-specific skills in<br />

response to employer promises, from their specialised know-how, which provides<br />

them with control over a valuable resource, <strong>and</strong> from the there<strong>of</strong> derived power <strong>and</strong><br />

influence over the firm.<br />

(3) Related institutional exposure. UCFs face exposure to employees in two forms: in<br />

the relationship with unionised workers <strong>and</strong> with regard to highly specialised<br />

knowledge bearers. <strong>The</strong> former depends on the local institutional environment <strong>and</strong> on<br />

the traditional firm-labour relations within the local culture, as well as the firm's own<br />

behaviour in the past <strong>and</strong> present. One <strong>of</strong> the major objectives <strong>of</strong> unions is to attain<br />

shifts in the firm's rent distribution towards unionised employees, e.g. by negotiating<br />

with employers over wages, working conditions <strong>and</strong> employment. Towards this end,<br />

unions may revert to strikes or boycotts as forms <strong>of</strong> hold-up <strong>and</strong> opportunism. In this<br />

context, UCFs' location-fixity, subadditive cost functions <strong>and</strong> sunk cost commitments<br />

103


104<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

in combination with their high public visibility contribute to their exposure towards<br />

unions <strong>and</strong> their rent appropriation efforts.<br />

To determine the firm's exposure towards highly skilled employees we distinguish<br />

between firms' investments in general-usage <strong>and</strong> in specific human capital, based on<br />

the transferability <strong>of</strong> employees' acquired skills 36 . Risk <strong>of</strong> hold-up thus arises from<br />

general investments in the sense that the acquired skills are valuable in trade with other<br />

parties, thus resulting in turnover costs to the firm. Hold-up exposure, however, also<br />

arises with regard to specific employee know-how to the effect that the firm will not<br />

easily be able to source the employee's know-how elsewhere, thus incurring high<br />

replacement <strong>and</strong> further specific investment costs. While this exposure is pertinent to<br />

all firms with a qualified labour force, it has considerable importance for UCF with<br />

respect to their highly specialised <strong>and</strong> complex industries, which require rare knowhow<br />

at their site <strong>of</strong> operation 37 .<br />

Public Stakeholders: the different roles <strong>of</strong> the government. Before proceeding with<br />

the individual public stakeholders, we will clarify the roles <strong>and</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> the<br />

sovereign for utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based industries. Historically, the nature <strong>of</strong><br />

UCIs' products, the resulting sub-additive cost function <strong>and</strong> their industry structures,<br />

which tend to encourage natural monopoly-status, have made them a focus <strong>of</strong><br />

governments <strong>and</strong> their institutions. While the latter are concerned with issues <strong>of</strong> larger<br />

national interest, such as market power, regulatory compliance, quality assurance <strong>and</strong><br />

productive efficiency, the firm's biggest concern is the protection <strong>of</strong> its asset-specific<br />

investments respectively recovery <strong>of</strong> its sunk cost. As a consequence, the relationship<br />

between firms <strong>and</strong> governments, classified as 'non-market relations' 38 , is characterised<br />

by mutual dependence <strong>and</strong> power. <strong>The</strong> aspect <strong>of</strong> power is particularly significant, since<br />

- contrary to other stakeholder relations - the government as sovereign has the<br />

monopoly <strong>of</strong> legitimate power, whereas the firm only is endowed with delegated<br />

36 This notion is borrowed from human capital theory, see also Kessler & Lülfesmann (2006).<br />

37<br />

This is exemplified by power utilities' need for engineering know-how in nuclear plant construction.<br />

Since the last nuclear plants in Switzerl<strong>and</strong> have been constructed in the 1960ies, the local industry is<br />

in desperate need for fresh expertise in view <strong>of</strong> the current plants' replacement. <strong>The</strong> same know-how<br />

shortage applies to the whole <strong>of</strong> Europe, where experts are rare while 300 nuclear plants will need to<br />

be completed until 2020 (interview N°3).<br />

38<br />

Interestingly, while these political factors are well integrated in international business research,<br />

mainstream organisation theory, strategic management research, <strong>and</strong> even the more recent<br />

organisational economics paradigm only consider external political behaviour, mostly treating political<br />

factors as constraints.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

power, resulting from its permission to operate within the bounds <strong>of</strong> government's<br />

sovereignty (Boddewyn & Brewer, 1994). Because <strong>of</strong> this unique constellation, the<br />

subsequent passages will elaborate in more detail the assumptions about the nature <strong>of</strong><br />

government <strong>and</strong> political actors.<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretically, government's decisions <strong>and</strong> activities always give highest priority to the<br />

public interest. This is ensured through adequate public governance, for example in the<br />

form <strong>of</strong> regulation, or through public corporate governance for firms with state<br />

participation (Schedler, Gulde, & Suter, 2007). Taking into account the diversity in<br />

government's organisation, its powers <strong>and</strong> responsibilities, firm-government relations<br />

in general are sufficiently complex, as manifested in<br />

- the differing sovereign functions <strong>of</strong> government, i.e. the legislative, executive<br />

<strong>and</strong> judiciary;<br />

- the multi-scalar involvement <strong>of</strong> government on local, regional <strong>and</strong> national<br />

scales;<br />

- the multiple levels <strong>of</strong> reference government institutions, such as ministries,<br />

departments, <strong>and</strong> agencies;<br />

- <strong>and</strong> the resulting multiplicity <strong>of</strong> roles, which government assumes.<br />

For the purpose <strong>of</strong> our research framework we have identified different roles <strong>of</strong><br />

government, which are relevant in its interaction with UCFs. <strong>The</strong>se roles range from<br />

its acting as regulator <strong>and</strong> guarantor <strong>of</strong> the State, as politician as per the political<br />

constellation <strong>of</strong> the sovereign system, its activities as promoter <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

development, <strong>and</strong> its market appearance as entrepreneur. Not surprisingly, these roles<br />

taken altogether contain a number <strong>of</strong> dilemmas <strong>of</strong> interest. Consequently, UCF face<br />

various forms <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure in their interactions with the sovereign, the<br />

significance <strong>of</strong> which being increased by the power differential between the parties.<br />

Table 4-5 provides an overview <strong>of</strong> government's objectives <strong>and</strong> related institutional<br />

exposure along the identified government functions.<br />

105


106<br />

Role <strong>of</strong> government as …<br />

objectives<br />

Regulator & guarantor<br />

maximisation <strong>of</strong> public welfare:<br />

general <strong>and</strong> sector-specific regulation<br />

(safety, quality, environment etc.) <strong>and</strong><br />

enforcement; avoidance <strong>of</strong> market power<br />

exploitation <strong>and</strong> price collusion<br />

Institutional exposure <strong>of</strong> UCF, due to …<br />

risk <strong>of</strong> over-regulation;<br />

exploitation <strong>of</strong> administrative discretion to the<br />

disadvantage <strong>of</strong> the firm<br />

ensuring compliance with law & order political influence on regulatory issues;<br />

yielding <strong>of</strong> regulator to public pressure or<br />

campaigning from interest groups<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

guarantor <strong>of</strong> supply <strong>and</strong> non-discrimination adverse effects on rent generation by obliging the firm<br />

to continue activities in economically unattractive<br />

fields at no or insufficient compensation<br />

Politician<br />

public governance:<br />

monitoring <strong>of</strong> firm-behaviour <strong>and</strong> perceived<br />

efforts towards the public good, respectively<br />

impairment there<strong>of</strong><br />

private agenda setting:<br />

mobilising voter-support within election<br />

cycle for<br />

re-election<br />

Promoter <strong>of</strong> economic development<br />

incentive-setting for economic investment:<br />

lender <strong>of</strong> capital with loans from state-owned<br />

banks; tax incentives; loan guarantees<br />

public shareholding for protection <strong>of</strong><br />

strategic national infrastructure <strong>and</strong><br />

security <strong>of</strong> supply<br />

Entrepreneur<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>it-oriented provision <strong>of</strong> public sector<br />

functions or related activities:<br />

buyer <strong>of</strong> output; supplier <strong>of</strong> raw materials or<br />

basic inputs; competitor through same-sector<br />

activities by state-owned enterprises (SOE)<br />

abuse <strong>of</strong> firm for political campaigning due to high<br />

visibility;<br />

scapegoating <strong>of</strong> firm to gain political capital<br />

reneging on governmental commitments due to shortterm<br />

fixation on election cycles;<br />

negotiation for the government representative's<br />

personal (i.e. political) instead <strong>of</strong> the public (longterm)<br />

interests<br />

hold-up resulting from dependence on state-borrowed<br />

capital <strong>and</strong> maturity transformation issues;<br />

hold-up in business development activities due to<br />

diverging risk-preferences between the firm <strong>and</strong> stateowned<br />

lenders<br />

weakening <strong>of</strong> revenue-base due to prioritisation <strong>of</strong><br />

short-term national economic interests at cost <strong>of</strong> the<br />

firm's long-term infrastructure re-financing (e.g. caps<br />

on regulated prices/fees)<br />

hold-up through bargaining power <strong>of</strong> SOE as critical<br />

business partner; weakening <strong>of</strong> revenue base through<br />

distorted competition from SOE, whose institutional<br />

relationship with the government gives them special<br />

advantages<br />

Table 4-5: Government's roles, objectives <strong>and</strong> related institutional exposure


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

On the basis <strong>of</strong> these roles, we proceed with the detailing <strong>of</strong> UCFs exposure towards<br />

the relevant public stakeholders, distinguishing the sovereign's functions as a<br />

shareholder, government, <strong>and</strong> as regulator.<br />

Public shareholders. (1) Definitional clarification. Ownership involvement <strong>of</strong> public<br />

bodies in firms frequently has historical roots, particularly in respect <strong>of</strong> utilities <strong>and</strong><br />

concession-based industries. Many industries have initially started out as purely stateowned,<br />

performing commercial activities on behalf <strong>of</strong> the government. In the past<br />

three decades, however, a number <strong>of</strong> countries initiated a liberalisation process within<br />

these industries, leading to the partial or full privatisation <strong>of</strong> SOEs. Terminologically,<br />

when we refer to public shareholders, we relate to public or government ownership as<br />

opposed to private or individual ownership. In the underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> our research<br />

framework, SOEs also include government-linked enterprises, i.e. firms which are<br />

partially owned by the state <strong>and</strong> where the public shareholder might also pursue public<br />

policy objectives.<br />

(2) Relation to research framework. <strong>The</strong> reasons for public ownership <strong>of</strong> firms are<br />

tw<strong>of</strong>old, according to Schedler et al. (2007): government either has a financial interest<br />

(i.e. expected financial returns) or it takes on a performance m<strong>and</strong>ate (e.g. on the basis<br />

<strong>of</strong> the firm's strategic relevance, or because <strong>of</strong> market distortions). Both motivations<br />

lend it high legitimacy as a stakeholder to the firm, normative <strong>and</strong> derived. Both<br />

motivations also get it into a field <strong>of</strong> tension between management <strong>and</strong> politics, from<br />

which three major responsibilities <strong>of</strong> the government may be derived (ibid.):<br />

- Management: it ensures, that the third party efficiently <strong>and</strong> effectively fulfils its<br />

tasks within the defined scope<br />

- Corporate Governance: as owner, government ensures the preservation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

firm's assets, control on the firm <strong>and</strong> its pr<strong>of</strong>itability<br />

- Public Governance: it guarantees the level <strong>of</strong> supply, legitimacy, legality <strong>and</strong><br />

has an eye on overall cost<br />

In fulfilment <strong>of</strong> these responsibilities the government delegates representatives to the<br />

firm's management board, thus taking influence on firm decisions <strong>and</strong> activities.<br />

(3) Related institutional exposure. However, government's involvement through the<br />

firm's board simultaneously creates an agency problem, since nobody ultimately<br />

monitors the political delegate in the pursuance <strong>of</strong> his m<strong>and</strong>ate. In addition Ferner<br />

(1988: 30) remarks with regard to SOEs, that “the way in which political objectives<br />

are defined through the political process <strong>and</strong> then ‘transmitted’ into the enterprise<br />

raises fundamental problems. … [T]he political dem<strong>and</strong>s on public enterprises lead to<br />

107


108<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

objectives that are confusing, changeable <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong>ten mutually at odds”. While - from<br />

the government's point <strong>of</strong> view - this ambiguity <strong>of</strong> objectives provides the firm's<br />

managers with discretion to pursue their own interests (Stiglitz & Heertje, 1989), the<br />

uncertainty which results from such political involvement is equally disturbing for the<br />

firm <strong>and</strong> creates institutional exposure.<br />

Furthermore, public policy objectives may also influence the risk tolerance <strong>of</strong> the<br />

public shareholder. As a consequence, the firm faces misaligned expectations between<br />

the public <strong>and</strong> the other shareholders, respectively the management regarding the<br />

firm's options for business development <strong>and</strong> growth.<br />

Regulator. (1) Definitional clarification. Regulation is the “sustained <strong>and</strong> focused<br />

control exercised by a public agency over activities that are valued by a community”<br />

(Selznick, 1985: 363).<br />

(2) Relation to research framework. <strong>The</strong> motivations for governments to regulate UCIs<br />

derive from issues like monopolisation, industry coordination <strong>and</strong> network effects,<br />

threats to human safety <strong>and</strong> the environment, impacts on overall economic<br />

development, <strong>and</strong> distributional concerns, i.e. the need to ensure universal access to<br />

basic commodities. <strong>The</strong>refore, society <strong>and</strong> consumers need some basic protection from<br />

negative public welfare impacts <strong>of</strong> the above issues. But much the same issues<br />

simultaneously dem<strong>and</strong> that firms' investments are protected, such as to ensure the<br />

quality <strong>of</strong> privately held strategic infrastructure <strong>and</strong> to avoid underinvestment. Finding<br />

a regulatory framework to effectively balance these complex interests against each<br />

other has proven to be intricate, even more so if political aspects <strong>and</strong> uncertainty with<br />

regard to long-term industry developments are taken into consideration.<br />

(3) Related institutional exposure. <strong>The</strong> institutional exposure <strong>of</strong> the UCF pertaining to<br />

regulation is concisely summarised by Migué (1977: 214), who describes regulation<br />

“as an instrument <strong>of</strong> wealth transfer - the extent <strong>of</strong> which is determined in a political<br />

market - where interest groups dem<strong>and</strong> regulation <strong>and</strong> politician-regulators supply it”.<br />

As a consequence <strong>of</strong> UCFs large sunk costs <strong>and</strong> the politicisation <strong>of</strong> their industries,<br />

they are prone to regulatory expropriation <strong>of</strong> their quasi-rents. In addition, as Joskow<br />

(1991: 68) argues, “the combination <strong>of</strong> franchise-specific sunk investments <strong>and</strong><br />

franchise exclusivity gives the regulatory agency (or more generally the political<br />

process to which it responds) potential power to hold up the utility”. Such<br />

expropriation may materialise for example in the regulator's price-setting below the<br />

firm's long-run average costs. But also more subtle forms are possible, for instance by<br />

requiring the firm to make specific investments or equipment purchases, or to accept


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

certain labour contracts that appropriate quasi-rents (Levy & Spiller, 1996).<br />

Furthermore, hold-up situations may result from the regulator's authority to certify the<br />

construction <strong>of</strong> major facility extensions <strong>and</strong> to disapprove incurred costs which he<br />

determines to be unreasonable ex post. Last but not least, the logic <strong>of</strong> 'obsolescing<br />

bargain' needs mentioning, which relates to governments' incentives to break longterm<br />

commitments with private investors, because they value agreements with them<br />

less attractive ex post than they seemed ex ante (Ramamurti, 2003).<br />

In summary, UCFs institutional exposure arises from the regulator's discretion through<br />

the principal-agent problem between the government <strong>and</strong> the regulator it m<strong>and</strong>ates.<br />

Relatively efficient regulatory rules require not only commitment, but also flexibility,<br />

thus granting the regulator substantial leeway in their application. <strong>The</strong>refore, according<br />

to Holburn <strong>and</strong> Spiller (2002: 470), the regulatory challenge “lies not just in designing<br />

regulatory incentive structures that restrain utilities' monopoly behavioural tendencies<br />

but also in designing regulatory governance frameworks that constrain the political<br />

<strong>and</strong> administrative actors who have ultimate jurisdiction over the industry”.<br />

Consequently, from a firm's perspective the credibility <strong>of</strong> the regulatory framework is<br />

decisive to determine its regulatory exposure: only if the firm is sufficiently reassured<br />

that the government <strong>and</strong> its regulator(s) restrain from using its discretionary power<br />

towards appropriating the utility's sunk investments, it will undertake efficient<br />

investments.<br />

Government. (1) Definitional clarification. Government is the “political system by<br />

which a body <strong>of</strong> people is administered <strong>and</strong> regulated” 39 . From a behavioural<br />

perspective, its parties <strong>and</strong> policies are the platform for politicians to be reelected,<br />

which is why political risk is among the greatest risks with regard to UCFs'<br />

institutional exposure. Moreover, governments <strong>of</strong>ten face a 'time consistency problem',<br />

since they “would be better <strong>of</strong>f in the long-term if they could commit not to<br />

expropriate investment returns, but face short-term incentives to do so” (Henisz &<br />

Zelner, 1999: 8).<br />

(2) Relation to research framework. With regard to their bargaining power towards<br />

governments, UCFs need to regard their sunk cost commitments over the asset's lifecycle.<br />

Over time, influence <strong>and</strong> bargaining power shifts between the two parties: while<br />

it is with the investor prior to the investment, i.e. when the government needs access to<br />

scarce capital or technology, bargaining power declines significantly after the UCF has<br />

39<br />

Government (2010). In Encyclopædia Britannica. Retrieved July 05, 2010, from Encyclopædia<br />

Britannica Online: www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/240105/government.<br />

109


110<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

sunk its capital. This decrease simultaneously increases the institutional exposure in<br />

the form <strong>of</strong> political risk, as a result <strong>of</strong> the government’s incentive to redistribute its<br />

returns to a broader set <strong>of</strong> interest groups (Henisz & Zelner, 2005). As a consequence,<br />

governments have a high normative <strong>and</strong> derived legitimacy as a stakeholder to the<br />

UCF, decisively influencing the latter's short- <strong>and</strong> long-term prosperity.<br />

(3) Related institutional exposure. Political risk thus relates less to rational preferences<br />

<strong>of</strong> the government as sovereign, but is defined by the individuals <strong>and</strong> parties<br />

representing the sovereign, their personal characteristics <strong>and</strong> preferences, as well as<br />

their political agenda. UCF's institutional exposure therefore needs to be reviewed - ex<br />

ante, but also on a continuous basis - based on factors like the structure <strong>of</strong> the political<br />

system, the credibility <strong>of</strong> policymakers’ commitment to a given policy regime, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

expected lobbying <strong>of</strong> affected interest groups as an indicator for possible reneging<br />

incentives. Henisz & Zelner (1999) further argue, that incentives for politicians to<br />

expropriate private investor's rents in the short term are rooted in UCFs' relatively<br />

small operating cost compared to the total costs. As a consequence, operators <strong>of</strong><br />

infrastructure assets continue their operation even when their revenue falls short <strong>of</strong> a<br />

sustainable economic return. An additional motivation for reneging comes from the<br />

electorate's preferences: due to UCFs' quasi-monopolistic status politicians may expect<br />

gains in political capital by accusing firms <strong>of</strong> market-power abuse, ensued by the<br />

appropriation <strong>of</strong> revenue-streams <strong>and</strong> rent re-distribution towards their providers <strong>of</strong><br />

political support.<br />

4.6.5 Reciprocal exposure, self-interest <strong>and</strong> the notion <strong>of</strong> fairness<br />

Thus far, firm-stakeholder relations <strong>and</strong> institutional exposure have been described<br />

uniquely from the UCF's perspective. For the sake <strong>of</strong> completeness, we would like to<br />

point out that such exposure <strong>of</strong>ten is mutual, with the UCF not only being a likely<br />

victim to opportunistic behaviour, but equally making use <strong>of</strong> its bargaining power to<br />

potentially hold up stakeholders. Such reciprocity <strong>of</strong> exposure <strong>and</strong> dependence brings<br />

up the notion <strong>of</strong> opportunism once again, <strong>and</strong> the conception <strong>of</strong> human behaviour. We<br />

therefore stipulate an alternative to the homo economicus, by outlining assumptions on<br />

the human nature, as <strong>of</strong>fered by the relational approaches within economic sociology<br />

<strong>and</strong> new institutionalism.<br />

To explain the opportunistic aspect <strong>of</strong> humans' self-interested utility maximisation,<br />

TCE added to the neoclassical conception the notion <strong>of</strong> guile, which Williamson<br />

circumscribes as “lying, stealing, cheating, <strong>and</strong> calculated efforts to mislead, distort,<br />

disguise, obfuscate, or otherwise confuse” (1985b: 47). While powerful in generating


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

predictions in many contexts <strong>of</strong> economic modelling, this conception adheres to a<br />

biased view <strong>of</strong> human behaviour 40 . This is particularly true for the assumption <strong>of</strong> pure<br />

self-interest, which proves weak in cases with few parties that interact strategically (as<br />

opposed to transactions in competitive markets) (Fehr & Schmidt, 2000). <strong>The</strong>refore<br />

the predominance <strong>of</strong> selfish motives in research is increasingly complemented by nonst<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

preferences, comprising considerations <strong>of</strong> fairness <strong>and</strong> reciprocity (T. Voss,<br />

2003). One <strong>of</strong> the keys to humans' bounded selfishness is the fact, that also<br />

opportunistic gains come at a cost, as for example social costs related to an impaired<br />

reputation or the loss <strong>of</strong> social legitimacy (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983). In support <strong>of</strong><br />

this notion, Hill (1990) suggests, that the invisible h<strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> the market does away with<br />

economic actors who have a reputation <strong>of</strong> being opportunistic, since selection<br />

mechanisms favour actors who display a consistent bias towards cooperation.<br />

As a consequence, research recently brought forward alternative theories <strong>of</strong> the firm,<br />

giving weight to the role <strong>of</strong> trust <strong>and</strong> trustworthiness in governing social <strong>and</strong> economic<br />

exchange (Tsai, 2000), <strong>and</strong> stressing the role <strong>of</strong> context in interactions. In various<br />

experiments it could be shown, for instance, that interacting people reciprocate each<br />

other's behaviour after an assessment <strong>of</strong> the interaction's fairness, i.e. that there is a<br />

“behavioural predisposition to cooperate conditionally on others’ cooperation <strong>and</strong> to<br />

punish violations <strong>of</strong> cooperative norms even at a net cost to the punisher” (Fehr &<br />

Gintis, 2007: 45; see also Bosse, Phillips, & Harrison, 2009). In other words,<br />

“reciprocity means that in response to friendly actions, people are frequently much<br />

nicer <strong>and</strong> much more cooperative than predicted by the self-interest model; conversely,<br />

in response to hostile actions they are frequently much more nasty <strong>and</strong> even brutal”<br />

(Fehr & Gächter, 2000: 159). Importantly, such reciprocal behaviour is not to be<br />

confounded with altruism, which is a form <strong>of</strong> unconditional kindness, or with<br />

retaliation, which is based on expectations <strong>of</strong> future material benefits as a result <strong>of</strong> the<br />

action. In contrast, reciprocal behaviour is a response to friendly or hostile actions, not<br />

connected to any expected gains. Moreover, actors evaluate their transaction partners<br />

not only on the basis <strong>of</strong> the outcome, but also based on their intentions. Intentionbased<br />

theories suggest “that people are generous only if they have been treated kindly,<br />

i.e., if the first-mover has signalled a fair intention” (Fehr & Schmidt, 2000: 34).<br />

With reference to our research model, reciprocity <strong>and</strong> to some extent the interpretation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the transaction party's intentions have important implications on governance<br />

40 This view is not only held by researchers in economic sociology <strong>and</strong> institutionalism, but also by a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> scholars in strategic management (e.g. Ghoshal, 2005; Wathne & Heide, 2000).<br />

111


112<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

mechanisms <strong>and</strong> on the enforcement <strong>of</strong> incomplete contracts. Moreover, these notions<br />

influence the firm's strategies <strong>and</strong> behaviour to reduce its institutional exposure <strong>and</strong> its<br />

opportunities to create value. Under the assumption <strong>of</strong> reciprocal behaviour in<br />

transactions, a firm may expect to some extent that its exemplary behaviour as a good<br />

corporate citizen will be appreciated by its stakeholders, who reciprocate the good<br />

intentions through equally benevolent attitudes <strong>and</strong> actions. Thus, reciprocal behaviour<br />

may change expected outcomes in principal-agent relations or in other transactions<br />

under uncertainty <strong>and</strong> asymmetric information, compared to the likely results<br />

assuming unbounded self-interest. This logic applies in inter-personal exchange, but<br />

also on an inter-organisational level (Bosse et al., 2009). We will explore this idea<br />

later in the development <strong>of</strong> our research model.<br />

4.6.6 Differences in institutional environment <strong>and</strong> political system<br />

Before continuing with the detailing <strong>of</strong> the research framework, we would like to<br />

underline the relevance <strong>of</strong> the firm's institutional <strong>and</strong> cultural context regarding<br />

stakeholder's propensity for opportunistic behaviour, <strong>and</strong> thus the firm's institutional<br />

exposure. Without considering the social context <strong>of</strong> the transaction partners <strong>and</strong> their<br />

transactions, “it is not possible to underst<strong>and</strong> whether agents will behave<br />

opportunistically or as a good steward” (Lubatkin, Lane, Collin, & Very, 2007: 51).<br />

<strong>The</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> context on economic actors' behaviour becomes even more pronounced<br />

when comparing different institutional <strong>and</strong> regulatory environments <strong>and</strong> cultural<br />

settings. Consequently, also the assessment <strong>of</strong> a firm's institutional exposure requires<br />

an underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the actors' social contexts <strong>and</strong> the nation's social <strong>and</strong> institutional<br />

setting. <strong>The</strong>se exogenous factors play a key role in creating assurance as to the<br />

expected actions <strong>of</strong> others (J. Walker & Ostrom, 2007), <strong>and</strong> differently organised<br />

societies <strong>and</strong> systems <strong>of</strong> institutions develop distinctive kinds <strong>of</strong> market rules <strong>and</strong><br />

actors. An example for the effects <strong>of</strong> such contextual variations is provided by Knack<br />

<strong>and</strong> Keefer (1997) in a comparison <strong>of</strong> different market economies, which led to the<br />

conclusion that “trust <strong>and</strong> norms <strong>of</strong> civic cooperation are stronger in countries with<br />

formal institutions that effectively protect property <strong>and</strong> contract rights, <strong>and</strong> in countries<br />

that are less polarised along lines <strong>of</strong> class or ethnicity” (ibid.: 1252). Because these<br />

systems are historically contingent, their strength, homogeneity <strong>and</strong> complementarities<br />

vary across countries <strong>and</strong> time, as does their ability to constrain opportunistic<br />

behaviour (Whitley, 2003).<br />

A review <strong>of</strong> the abundant scientific literature on institutional <strong>and</strong> contextual<br />

differences, <strong>and</strong> their effects on economic behaviour would be beyond the scope <strong>of</strong> our


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

dissertation. Nonetheless, we would like to stress the relevance <strong>of</strong> (institutional, social,<br />

cultural) contexts with regard to the modelled framework. Since the case studies for<br />

our empirical research are all set in strongly developed institutional environments,<br />

with pronounced trust in the legal system <strong>and</strong> strong protection <strong>of</strong> property rights, they<br />

do not allow inferences pertaining to other (i.e. weaker) institutional contexts. Yet, we<br />

stipulate that the general relations within our research model remain valid in all<br />

institutional <strong>and</strong> cultural contexts, while the emphasis <strong>and</strong> relevance <strong>of</strong> certain<br />

elements might shift along changing idiosyncratic local contexts.<br />

4.7 Moderators <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure<br />

In assessing the relation between the firm's location-fixity <strong>and</strong> its institutional<br />

exposure, our empirical research brought forward indications that there are two<br />

moderators <strong>of</strong> relevance: the firm's local economic relevance <strong>and</strong> its competitive<br />

environment. <strong>The</strong>se moderating factors will be assessed in more detail in the following<br />

sections.<br />

local exposure<br />

location fixity<br />

local economic<br />

relevance <strong>of</strong> firm<br />

competitive<br />

environment<br />

(4.7.1)<br />

(4.7.2)<br />

institutional exposure<br />

Figure 4-7: Moderators between location-fixity <strong>and</strong> institutional exposure<br />

4.7.1 <strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> the local economic relevance on institutional exposure<br />

In performing their activities, firms - <strong>and</strong> in particular UCFs - are in a state <strong>of</strong> mutual<br />

dependence with their local environment. On one h<strong>and</strong>, the firm depends on regional<br />

factors, such as public infrastructure, the local labour market, <strong>and</strong> institutional context<br />

factors, whose overall attractiveness influences the firm's bottom line <strong>and</strong> its future<br />

development potentials. On the other side, the region benefits from, <strong>and</strong> in certain<br />

cases depends on the firm <strong>and</strong> its local production. <strong>The</strong> degree, to which a firm's<br />

activity is vital for its environment is partially determined by its industry affiliation,<br />

which is why UCI <strong>of</strong>ten are <strong>of</strong> high relevance as industries in the public interest.<br />

113


114<br />

Example: Zurich Airport's effects on regional economic development<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

In a study on the economic relevance <strong>of</strong> the Swiss aviation sector for the national economy, the<br />

consultancy firm Infras (2006) calculated the direct <strong>and</strong> indirect economic effects <strong>of</strong> Zurich Airport to<br />

total CHF 3.9bn per annum, respectively employment effects amounting to 24'000 full time equivalents<br />

(FTE). Under consideration <strong>of</strong> the wider <strong>and</strong> thus less causal effects, the total economic relevance <strong>of</strong><br />

the airport is estimated to total CHF 9.9bn per annum, respectively 68'000 FTE. Although such<br />

calculations may vary depending on the underlying assumptions, they indicate the significance <strong>of</strong> the<br />

infrastructure for the regional economy.<br />

Apart from the quantifiable value-contributing effects <strong>of</strong> airports, also qualitative effects need to be<br />

taken into account, such as (ibid.)<br />

- the expansion <strong>of</strong> market reach <strong>and</strong> related economies <strong>of</strong> scale,<br />

- the expansion <strong>of</strong> employment markets <strong>and</strong> related access to highly qualified workforce<br />

- a potential increase <strong>of</strong> competitive pressure in a number <strong>of</strong> industries, due to market access<br />

for competitors<br />

- an efficient global exchange <strong>of</strong> goods <strong>and</strong> services, which facilitates investments <strong>of</strong> Swiss firms<br />

abroad <strong>and</strong> foreign direct investment in Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

- a significant contribution to the international accessibility <strong>of</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong> as a business<br />

location, which supports key industries such as Switzerl<strong>and</strong>'s financial sector <strong>and</strong> the<br />

attractiveness as a location for research <strong>and</strong> science (cf. Bleisch, 2005)<br />

Because <strong>of</strong> the airport's role for the attractiveness <strong>of</strong> the Greater Zurich Area as a business location,<br />

<strong>and</strong> thus for the development <strong>of</strong> the local economy, the preservation <strong>of</strong> its functionality <strong>and</strong> quality are<br />

legally anchored in the Airport Law <strong>of</strong> the Canton <strong>of</strong> Zurich. <strong>The</strong> first paragraph there<strong>of</strong> states: “<strong>The</strong><br />

State promotes Zurich Airport in order to preserve its economic <strong>and</strong> transport-related interests” 41 .<br />

This principal support with regard to economic interests, however, is subsequently contained by<br />

setting it against the needs <strong>of</strong> the surrounding inhabitants, <strong>and</strong> the first paragraph continues by stating<br />

“It thereby takes into account the protection <strong>of</strong> the population with regard to detrimental or<br />

undesirable effects <strong>of</strong> airport operations” ("Flughafengesetz," ibid.). As a consequence, Zurich<br />

Airport's institutional exposure is reduced in relation to its going concern <strong>and</strong> functionality. However,<br />

in view <strong>of</strong> its development opportunities <strong>and</strong> future outlook, the same legal fundament, politics <strong>and</strong> the<br />

local administration have a limiting effect.<br />

Furthermore, the firm's local importance is inversely related to the region's degree <strong>of</strong><br />

economic development <strong>and</strong> accessibility. Stated differently, in remote regions with<br />

scarce economic activities, a firm's relevance for the local livelihoods may be<br />

significant. Also in this regard UCFs frequently are vital local economic contributors,<br />

as a number <strong>of</strong> them needs to settle in structurally weak regions due to their resourcedependence<br />

or the nature <strong>of</strong> their product (e.g. hydro-electric power generation,<br />

41 "Der Staat fördert den Flughafen Zürich zur Sicherstellung seiner volks- und verkehrswirtschaftlichen<br />

Interessen. Er berücksichtigt dabei den Schutz der Bevölkerung vor schädlichen oder lästigen<br />

Auswirkungen des Flughafenbetriebs" ("Flughafengesetz," 1999: §1).


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

mining, cement <strong>and</strong> clinker production). As a consequence, the firm <strong>and</strong> the local<br />

environment develop an apprehension <strong>of</strong> their mutual dependence, with the local<br />

stakeholders being anxious to ensure the firm's well-being <strong>and</strong> to uphold its interest in<br />

the location. From a power-balance perspective, such economic relevance should<br />

result in a decrease in the firm's institutional exposure. This power imbalance,<br />

however, is mitigated by the firm's reliance on the local resource <strong>and</strong> its strategic<br />

alternatives to the local production site. <strong>The</strong> ensuing example illustrates the effects <strong>of</strong><br />

regional dependence on the firm, <strong>and</strong> the firm's reliance on a scarce local resource on<br />

its institutional exposure.<br />

Example: Institutional exposure in structurally weak regions - Axpo Hydropower project in Linth-<br />

Limmern<br />

<strong>The</strong> Axpo Group, being Switzerl<strong>and</strong>’s leading energy utility, stresses its strong local roots <strong>and</strong> its<br />

focus on sustainable energy. Consequently, in March 2005 Axpo started one <strong>of</strong> its most significant<br />

hydropower projects – “Linthal 2015” - involving a CHF 2.1bn investment volume <strong>and</strong> upgrading the<br />

existing hydropower plant to pump <strong>and</strong> turbine capacities <strong>of</strong> 1000 MW each. Despite the project's<br />

complexity Axpo advanced in all administrative approval processes with no major hurdles. It obtained<br />

the concession for the pump-storage plant in March 2009 <strong>and</strong> shortly later the building permit in July<br />

2009. Three major factors for the successful h<strong>and</strong>ling <strong>of</strong> the concession process can be identified:<br />

- the economic structure <strong>of</strong> the region: Linthal belongs to the canton <strong>of</strong> Glarus <strong>and</strong> is an<br />

economically <strong>and</strong> structurally weakly developed region, the project will significantly spur<br />

local economic development<br />

- the extensive local embeddedness <strong>of</strong> Axpo's local subsidiary Kraftwerke Linth-Limmern AG<br />

(KLL): KLL historically is an important economic factor in the region; it is deeply embedded<br />

in its environment <strong>and</strong> actively manages its stakeholder relations<br />

- the early involvement <strong>of</strong> project stakeholders: KLL involved the relevant stakeholders from<br />

the very beginning, most importantly the local administration <strong>and</strong> environmental interest<br />

groups; Axpo regards their early <strong>and</strong> sincere inclusion as key to project success<br />

In a project newsletter the company cites its director <strong>of</strong> the board, Robert Lombardini: “<strong>The</strong> biggest<br />

construction project is also the most significant for the canton Glarus. Correspondingly the<br />

commitment is high on both sides” (Axpo Hydro Energie, 2009). <strong>The</strong> project secures the canton a one-<br />

<strong>of</strong>f income <strong>of</strong> CHF 62m in concession fees alone, plus an annual CHF 8 to 10m from taxes, power<br />

proceeds <strong>and</strong> dividends, not to mention the primary <strong>and</strong> secondary effects on the region. However, due<br />

to the low pr<strong>of</strong>it earning capacity <strong>of</strong> pump storage stations the long-term re-financing <strong>and</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>itability<br />

<strong>of</strong> the project need to be carefully guarded with respect to local stakeholders' rent-appropriation.<br />

Despite the high stakes for some <strong>of</strong> the affected municipalities <strong>and</strong> their dependence on the project, the<br />

region succeeded to appropriate a significant portion <strong>of</strong> the project's present value, suggesting that<br />

the firm's dependence on the project outweighs the region's high economic interest in the firm's<br />

activities (cf. interview N°3: 14). Possible explanations could be the scarcity <strong>of</strong> suitable hydropower<br />

sites <strong>of</strong> this magnitude, the state's agenda for energy policy (strongly encouraging an increase in the<br />

115


116<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

share <strong>of</strong> renewable power in the firm's energy mix), <strong>and</strong> the pressure on Axpo from its sovereign<br />

supply m<strong>and</strong>ate. In addition the local administration made use <strong>of</strong> its negotiation power before the<br />

project's approval, being aware that opportunities for quasi-rent appropriation need to be exploited<br />

prior to the award <strong>of</strong> concession. Once the contracts are signed, such opportunities become rare, if<br />

one excludes the options <strong>of</strong> contract-breach or opportunistic ex-post renegotiation.<br />

Based on indications from our empirical research, we therefore derive a proposition<br />

with regard to the effect <strong>of</strong> firms' local economic relevance <strong>and</strong> institutional exposure.<br />

Proposition 7<br />

<strong>The</strong> institutional exposure <strong>of</strong> the UCF is moderated by its role <strong>and</strong> importance within<br />

the local economy, on the basis <strong>of</strong> its industry nature or its contribution to the local<br />

livelihood.<br />

Since a thorough analysis <strong>of</strong> the mitigating effects <strong>of</strong> the firm's local relevance on its<br />

institutional exposure would be beyond the scope <strong>of</strong> this dissertation, we commend<br />

such analysis for further exploration <strong>and</strong> verification to future research.<br />

4.7.2 <strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> competition on institutional exposure<br />

<strong>The</strong> second moderator, which we identified in the relationship between location-fixity<br />

<strong>and</strong> institutional exposure, warrants further elaboration <strong>and</strong> we consequently introduce<br />

it with caution. In our empirical research a number <strong>of</strong> explanatory approaches<br />

emerged, partly contradicting, <strong>and</strong> with no attainable saturation throughout the<br />

research process. Since the feedback in our case studies affirmed the influence <strong>of</strong> the<br />

moderator by <strong>and</strong> large, it consequently has been integrated in our research model. <strong>The</strong><br />

three different explanatory approaches, which depend on the firm's conduct towards its<br />

competitors, will be laid out below.<br />

Firms <strong>and</strong> competitors cooperate to limit stakeholder's rent-appropriation. Firms<br />

under significant pressure from their stakeholders, e.g. due to their externalities, might<br />

benefit from the advent <strong>of</strong> other market players. As a single player, a firm whose<br />

activities impact the local environment risks to face undivided stakeholder attention<br />

<strong>and</strong> criticism. In addition, its high visibility might make it a rewarding target in order<br />

to gain political capital. With the presence <strong>of</strong> more than one competing player, also the<br />

externalities no longer are clearly attributable to one emitter (e.g. fly-over noise in<br />

multi-airport cities). Since these now are the product <strong>of</strong> several industry peers, political<br />

<strong>and</strong> public pressure on the single firm decrease.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Furthermore, the competing players may decide to cooperate with regard to<br />

stakeholder issues, thus being able to find joint solutions, or to bring forward their<br />

arguments more convincingly through joint communication <strong>and</strong> lobbying efforts, as<br />

illustrated by the subsequent examples.<br />

Example: Competitor collaboration against political hold-up - airport privatisation in India<br />

In face <strong>of</strong> the significant investments needed for developing its airport infrastructure, India decided to<br />

start privatising its airports at the turn <strong>of</strong> the millennium. In the early privatisation process, two<br />

greenfield airports in South India served as pilot-projects for the government to collected experiences<br />

in Public Private Partnerships (PPP) <strong>and</strong> to determine the regulatory set-up. During this regulatory<br />

transition phase, negotiations with the various governmental bodies were characterised with<br />

significant regulatory discretion <strong>and</strong> uncertainty. A pivotal issue for the private investors was the<br />

determination <strong>of</strong> the newly introduced User Development Fee (UDF), a regulated charge needed for<br />

the financing <strong>of</strong> the new airport infrastructure <strong>and</strong> future extension projects. For both pilot projects,<br />

the Bengaluru International Airport (BIA) <strong>and</strong> Hyderabad's Rajiv G<strong>and</strong>hi International Airport (HIA),<br />

the government assured that UDF was to be calculated on the basis <strong>of</strong> audited project costs within a<br />

contractually binding time frame. However, for both airports the Indian authorities granted a UDF<br />

significantly below those calculated needs. As an additional drawback to its refinancing, the operator<br />

<strong>of</strong> BIA waited for a formal go-ahead to levy the UDF for more than six months, which led to initial<br />

cash flow <strong>and</strong> debt-servicing problems. In response to this threat to infrastructure refinancing the two<br />

competing airport projects started to coordinate their actions <strong>and</strong> argumentation towards the relevant<br />

authorities, which ultimately led to the approval <strong>of</strong> an acceptable, albeit lower than expected UDF for<br />

both airports.<br />

Example: Competitor collaboration to gain argumentative clout<br />

<strong>The</strong> electrical power sector in Switzerl<strong>and</strong> consists <strong>of</strong> a few major players, including Alpiq, Axpo,<br />

BKW, <strong>and</strong> Rätia. For historical reasons their mutual relations are co-opetitive, as partners in the<br />

production process, <strong>and</strong> as competitors in the market for electricity. With the help <strong>of</strong> the industry<br />

association “Swisselectric” they coordinate their interests with the objective to take influence on the<br />

political <strong>and</strong> regulatory issues, as per the interest <strong>of</strong> the members. Such pooling <strong>of</strong> resources <strong>and</strong><br />

harmonisation <strong>of</strong> positions through an association thus allows effective lobbying within the political<br />

system to decrease institutional exposure <strong>and</strong> to attain mutual economic gain.<br />

Thus we derive the following propositions:<br />

Proposition 8<br />

Institutional exposure decreases in an environment with local competitors, if the UCF<br />

cooperates with competitors with regard to stakeholder issues <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

117


118<br />

Proposition 9<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Institutional exposure decreases in an environment with local competitors, because<br />

industry-specific externalities originate from several industry players, which reduces<br />

incentives to dispraise a single firm.<br />

Firms' individual efforts for stakeholder goodwill increase with competition.<br />

Under competition local stakeholders have the possibility to compare rivalling players'<br />

conduct <strong>and</strong> their approaches to stakeholder issues. As a consequence, industry players<br />

need to increase activities aimed at maintaining their local 'licence to operate', <strong>and</strong> to<br />

build goodwill stocks with the local community as a means for competitor<br />

differentiation. Since UCFs usually depend on scarce local resources, new project<br />

opportunities in the region are expected to be contested among the industry players. In<br />

view <strong>of</strong> such future development opportunities, firms therefore hope to increase their<br />

chances for award <strong>of</strong> project through favourable conduct <strong>and</strong> reputation-building<br />

activities. Through this embedding process, firms develop a competitive edge allowing<br />

it to generate quasi-rents, which are then partly bargained away by the community in<br />

which it is embedded. Based on this argumentation two further propositions are added:<br />

Proposition 10<br />

A high level <strong>of</strong> competition leads to an increase in institutional exposure, due to<br />

stakeholders' possibility to play competing firms <strong>of</strong>f against each other.<br />

Rent-dissipation in oligopolistic competition. Last but not least, we would like to<br />

introduce the notion <strong>of</strong> 'War <strong>of</strong> Attrition', originating from game theory, as an<br />

alternative approach to explain the effects <strong>of</strong> competition on firms' institutional<br />

exposure <strong>and</strong> rent distribution. A 'War <strong>of</strong> attrition', in the sense <strong>of</strong> an 'industry<br />

shakeout' (Bulow & Klemperer, 1999), refers to a competitive situation in which the<br />

contestants earn no rents <strong>and</strong> sell their products at average cost, with the objective to<br />

survive until the other contestant exits the market (Fudenberg & Tirole, 1987).<br />

Consequently, if all above average returns are competed away by the industry players,<br />

the individual firm's institutional exposure decreases, since it becomes less attractive<br />

for rent appropriation through stakeholders. Such a firm may fend <strong>of</strong>f stakeholder<br />

claims by arguing that it needs to protect its future livelihood <strong>and</strong> competitiveness. In<br />

contrast, a single firm enjoying monopolistic above-average returns faces an increased<br />

institutional exposure, since stakeholders would try to appropriate the composite


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

quasi-rent, thus endangering the firm's sustainable long-term development. Figure 4-8<br />

illustrates the logic <strong>of</strong> the 'War <strong>of</strong> Attrition', whereby the operators beneath the arrows<br />

indicate a positive or negative influence.<br />

local stakeholders<br />

appropriation <strong>of</strong> quasi-rent<br />

firm<br />

value-creating +<br />

rent<br />

competition<br />

economic activities<br />

−<br />

rent dissipation in War <strong>of</strong> Attrition:<br />

competition on resources & price<br />

Figure 4-8: Influence <strong>of</strong> aggressive competition on institutional exposure<br />

−<br />

+<br />

institutional<br />

exposure<br />

We therefore infer, that the relation between a firm's appropriable rent <strong>and</strong> its<br />

institutional exposure are positively reinforcing, leading to our next proposition:<br />

Proposition 11<br />

<strong>The</strong> lower (higher) the firm's appropriable rent, the lower (higher) is its institutional<br />

exposure.<br />

Explanatory ambiguity <strong>of</strong> 'competitive environment' as moderator <strong>of</strong><br />

institutional exposure. In view <strong>of</strong> the different approaches towards explaining the<br />

effects <strong>of</strong> competition on firms' institutional exposure, we have to concede that it is<br />

impossible to draw unambiguous conclusions within the scope <strong>of</strong> our empirical<br />

research. Instead, we make a universally valid inference by asserting the relevance <strong>of</strong><br />

the competitive environment to our research model 42 . Further clarification <strong>of</strong> this<br />

moderator's influence on the relation between location-fixity <strong>and</strong> institutional<br />

exposure, however, is commended to future research projects.<br />

4.8 Embedding capabilities <strong>of</strong> local management<br />

In the preceding analysis <strong>of</strong> local exposure, we conceptually clarified the<br />

characteristics <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> the resulting institutional exposure for UCF, in<br />

42 This general inference is supported by Cox (1995), who suggested in his article on "Globalisation,<br />

competition <strong>and</strong> the politics <strong>of</strong> local economic development" that the relation between competition <strong>and</strong><br />

local dependence should be explored at greater length.<br />

119


120<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

order to underst<strong>and</strong> their specific context. On both constructs, the firm has no direct<br />

influence: they are exogenous <strong>and</strong> represent the independent coefficients <strong>of</strong> the model<br />

- however, they may have very real effects on the firm's pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>and</strong> its future<br />

value creation potential. In the next section, we turn our focus on the firm's<br />

possibilities to mitigate these real <strong>and</strong> potential effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong><br />

institutional exposure. By analysing the dimensions <strong>of</strong> the firm's embedding<br />

capabilities as a moderator to these effects, we define the action parameter <strong>of</strong> our<br />

research framework.<br />

local exposure<br />

from location fixity<br />

embedding<br />

capabilities (4.8)<br />

moderate<br />

influences<br />

value creation<br />

independent coefficient action parameter dependent (output) variable<br />

Figure 4-9: Embedding capabilities as action parameter towards value creation<br />

By means <strong>of</strong> its embedding capabilities, the firm is able to work towards two distinct<br />

objectives with regard to its local exposure. On one h<strong>and</strong>, it may deploy them to (1)<br />

avert potential damage <strong>and</strong> risk through stakeholders, who exploit their power<br />

differentials <strong>and</strong> thus have an inherent threat potential. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, they may<br />

use these capabilities to (2) mobilise stakeholder support <strong>and</strong> to safeguard future<br />

development options. Both <strong>of</strong> these objectives affect its potential to create value <strong>and</strong> to<br />

increase its competitive advantage, as illustrated in Figure 4-10.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

local<br />

exposure<br />

threat<br />

potential<br />

support<br />

potential<br />

(1)<br />

(2)<br />

objectives <strong>of</strong><br />

embedding capabilities<br />

forestall value destruction<br />

avert damage<br />

reduce risk<br />

enable value creation<br />

mobilise stakeholder<br />

support<br />

safeguard<br />

future options<br />

Figure 4-10: Objectives <strong>of</strong> the firm's embedding capabilities<br />

effects on<br />

value creation<br />

net value<br />

creation<br />

competitive<br />

advantage<br />

In the elaboration <strong>of</strong> the elements which form part <strong>of</strong> the firm's embedding<br />

capabilities, we will particularly be guided by the theoretical lenses <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

geography, institutional economics <strong>and</strong> strategic management.<br />

<strong>The</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> organisational legitimacy. In their activities, all firms are - to<br />

various degrees - dependent on resources, such a materials, labour <strong>and</strong> capital, but also<br />

on abstract goods like political stability, a dependable judicial system <strong>and</strong> -<br />

importantly - legitimacy in the eyes <strong>of</strong> the public (Dyllick, 1984). Under consideration<br />

<strong>of</strong> the long-term orientation <strong>of</strong> our research object, its locational dependence <strong>and</strong> its<br />

high visibility, this last-mentioned aspect <strong>of</strong> legitimacy becomes particularly relevant<br />

as UCF substantially depend on the goodwill <strong>of</strong> their surrounding stakeholders. As a<br />

consequence <strong>of</strong> their special characteristics, they therefore can be considered<br />

“creatures <strong>of</strong> public authority” (Jepperson & Meyer, 1991: 206), which continuously<br />

need to prove their justification for exposing their environment to various externalities.<br />

We therefore regard corporate legitimacy as a critical resource to the UCF, which is<br />

provided through the local institutional environment giving “cultural support to<br />

organisations ... in the form <strong>of</strong> acceptance” (Oinas, 1995: 155). Furthermore, corporate<br />

legitimacy is critical, since it may impact the firm's value creation opportunities (as<br />

will be elaborated later), since it is rare <strong>and</strong> inimitable in the sense, that it has to be<br />

achieved over time <strong>and</strong> cannot be built systematically, <strong>and</strong> since it is imperfectly<br />

substitutable for UCFs due to their local fixation <strong>and</strong> given stakeholder set-up. As a<br />

consequence, legitimacy even qualifies as a strategic resource, fulfilling all criteria <strong>of</strong><br />

121


122<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

RBV’s VRIN framework. Thus, earning <strong>and</strong> keeping a stakeholder 'licence to<br />

operate' 43 becomes a factor for sustained competitive advantage for location-fixed<br />

companies, which they should integrate accordingly in the management <strong>of</strong> the<br />

relations with their institutional environment: “if stakeholders are to feel <strong>and</strong> act<br />

positively towards a company, it will be in reciprocation for that company making a<br />

contribution to their lives” (Lewis, 2001: 35).<br />

Embeddedness as a means towards building legitimacy. <strong>The</strong> degree to which a<br />

company is legitimised by its environment predominantly depends on its<br />

embeddedness within its local context. <strong>The</strong> process <strong>of</strong> embedding is understood as<br />

“the way in which organisations or actors become tied in to the local business <strong>and</strong><br />

institutional environment” (Alderman, 2004: 256). Importantly, unlike the externally<br />

driven organisational legitimacy, embeddedness can be actively fostered by the firm<br />

(cf. next section). It represents an indirect means to increase its legitimacy <strong>and</strong><br />

acceptance within its local environment.<br />

4.8.1 <strong>The</strong> concept <strong>of</strong> embeddedness<br />

<strong>The</strong> notion <strong>of</strong> embeddedness found its way into broader economic thinking through<br />

Granovetter's seminal work 'Economic action <strong>and</strong> social structure: <strong>The</strong> problem <strong>of</strong><br />

embeddedness' (1985). It takes account <strong>of</strong> the significant social elements contained in<br />

all economic action <strong>and</strong> stresses the fact that “economic action <strong>and</strong> outcomes, like all<br />

social action <strong>and</strong> outcomes, are affected by actors' dyadic relations <strong>and</strong> by the structure<br />

<strong>of</strong> overall network <strong>of</strong> relations” (Grabher, 1993: 4) 44 . In a wider context, the<br />

embeddedness concept is linked to the institutional perspective, basing on the postulate<br />

that social relations are shaped <strong>and</strong> constrained by informal (traditions, customs, etc.)<br />

<strong>and</strong> formal institutions (organisations, administrative systems, etc.). For firms,<br />

embeddedness to their local environment therefore may entail constraints (e.g. in the<br />

form <strong>of</strong> 'institutional thickness', cf. Amin & Thrift, 1994), just as it is conducive to<br />

significant strategic opportunities (Dacin et al., 1999). <strong>The</strong>se result from the fact, that<br />

the firm's embedding process is reciprocally influenced by activities <strong>of</strong> the firm itself,<br />

<strong>and</strong> by the behaviour <strong>of</strong> strategic actors. Thus, by underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>and</strong> adapting to its<br />

43<br />

A term borrowed from Holcim, which aims in its community involvement programmes to maintain<br />

its " 'license to operate' by providing education for society’s future, building infrastructure for liveable<br />

communities, supporting sustainable community development" (Otto, 2006: 18).<br />

44<br />

<strong>The</strong> value <strong>of</strong> a firm's relations with its environment for its competitive position is also<br />

acknowledged within the RBV, as manifested in Rumelt's (1974: 557) statement that "a firm's<br />

competitive position is defined by a bundle <strong>of</strong> unique resources <strong>and</strong> relationships [emphasis added]".


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

cultural <strong>and</strong> institutional context, the firm is able to bound the range <strong>of</strong> possible<br />

organisational actions, in order to specifically enhance its embeddedness. As a<br />

consequence, the firm's active fostering <strong>of</strong> its local embedding may open<br />

opportunities, while it may build strategic barriers for other competitive players.<br />

Conceptual ambiguity <strong>of</strong> embeddedness. Despite extensive research within various<br />

fields <strong>of</strong> research, embeddedness unfortunately remains an ambiguous notion<br />

resonating between under- <strong>and</strong> over-socialised conceptualisations (Oinas, 1997). Pike<br />

et al. (2000) remark the term as being over-used in careless ways that <strong>of</strong>ten empty it <strong>of</strong><br />

much <strong>of</strong> its meaning. Nevertheless, “it serves a function in opening up a number <strong>of</strong><br />

questions concerning the nature <strong>of</strong> economic action <strong>and</strong> the relations <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

actors with their socio-spatial environments” (Oinas, 1997: 24). A review <strong>of</strong> the<br />

existing literature on embeddedness reveals differing terminological interpretations<br />

<strong>and</strong>, above all, the need <strong>of</strong> a few clarifications on the scaling <strong>of</strong> the term (on a timespace<br />

scale), the further specification <strong>of</strong> the actors in embedding processes, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

dimensions <strong>of</strong> analysis in order to disentangle the “reciprocal social, political <strong>and</strong><br />

economic processes that occur at multiple scales <strong>and</strong> change constantly at any given<br />

scale” (Hayter, 2004: 99). Some <strong>of</strong> the reasons, why a clear conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

embeddedness construct is so challenging are subsumed as follows:<br />

- embeddedness consists <strong>of</strong> multiple layers <strong>and</strong> dimensions, which are partly<br />

overlapping <strong>and</strong> hence not easy to conceptually separate<br />

- embeddedness entails institutional <strong>and</strong> economic processes (cf. Dacin et al.,<br />

1999), respectively social <strong>and</strong> an economic components “symbiotically<br />

integrated, only understood in relation to one another” (Hayter, 2004: 98),<br />

- embeddedness consists <strong>of</strong> a time-space scale, since “becoming embedded … as<br />

well as sustaining embeddedness is a process (<strong>of</strong> longer duration)” (Oinas,<br />

1997: 28) <strong>and</strong> embedding relates to a spatial scale, ranging from local to more<br />

geographically distant ways <strong>of</strong> embedding<br />

- the actors in economic embeddedness are not entirely clear, as there remains<br />

uncertainty if the embedding process is rather driven by individuals or also by<br />

institutions as collective actors<br />

- the embedding <strong>of</strong> actors is a reciprocal process<br />

- embedding is not a one-directional process <strong>and</strong> can reverse into disembedding<br />

Social <strong>and</strong> economic aspects <strong>of</strong> embeddedness. To resolve some <strong>of</strong> these<br />

ambiguities, Zukin <strong>and</strong> DiMaggio (1990) in their seminal work 'Structures <strong>of</strong> Capital:<br />

<strong>The</strong> Social Organization <strong>of</strong> the Economy' classify four forms <strong>of</strong> embeddedness:<br />

123


124<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

structural, cognitive, cultural <strong>and</strong> political-institutional 45 . Albeit very useful to<br />

disentangle some <strong>of</strong> the complexities <strong>of</strong> the concept, the authors equate 'structural'<br />

with 'social' embeddedness as contextualisation <strong>of</strong> economic exchange in patterns <strong>of</strong><br />

ongoing interpersonal relations. Thus, they leave one <strong>of</strong> the main complexities <strong>of</strong> the<br />

concept unresolved, as pointed out by Hayter's (2004) appeal to underst<strong>and</strong> the<br />

symbiotic relationship <strong>of</strong> the social <strong>and</strong> the economic components <strong>of</strong> embeddedness,<br />

<strong>and</strong> as further reinforced by Oinas (as cited in Pike et al., 2000: 20):<br />

Even though the ‘economic’ <strong>and</strong> the ‘social’ seem intertwined <strong>and</strong> inseparable<br />

from one another empirically, it does not mean that we could not <strong>and</strong> should<br />

not analytically separate ‘the economic’ from the rest <strong>of</strong> what is ‘social’, even<br />

though it might be difficult in some instances.<br />

<strong>The</strong> distinction between the economic <strong>and</strong> social aspects <strong>of</strong> embeddedness, however,<br />

is crucial to our own conception <strong>of</strong> embeddedness in the context <strong>of</strong> the organisational<br />

embedding capabilities to foster a value-enhancing business environment (cf. section<br />

4.8.3).<br />

Spatial Scale. From the perspective <strong>of</strong> economic geography, “economic events are<br />

necessarily contextual, that is embedded in spatial structures <strong>of</strong> social relations” (R.<br />

Martin, 1994: 42). To take account <strong>of</strong> the spatial scale <strong>of</strong> embeddedness, Oinas (1997)<br />

conceptualises the construct as local, regional, or relations over a longer distance with<br />

varying intensities. Actors interacting on the same spatial scale may be characterised<br />

as locally embedded, whereas embeddedness on an extra-local scale is referred to as<br />

spatial embeddedness (ibid.). With reference to our research framework, the focus lies<br />

on local embeddedness <strong>of</strong> our research object, i.e. the local firm's relations with its<br />

local stakeholders. Depending on the firm's industry structure <strong>and</strong> geographical<br />

organisation, the spatial scale <strong>of</strong> its embedding activities may also extend from the<br />

local to regional or national levels, as for example in the firm's relations to regional<br />

public administrations or national regulatory bodies.<br />

Actors in the embedding process. <strong>The</strong> concept <strong>of</strong> embeddedness relates to<br />

individuals in interaction with their environment, as well as to collective actors, such<br />

as firms, units <strong>of</strong> a firm, or networks. A firm's local embeddedness “is <strong>of</strong>ten a result <strong>of</strong><br />

a combination <strong>of</strong> individual <strong>and</strong> collective embeddedness” (Oinas, 1997: 27), whereby<br />

individuals <strong>and</strong> their actions reflect the organisations within <strong>and</strong> through which they<br />

45 For an immersed discussion on embeddedness see also Dacin, Ventresca, & Beal (1999).


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

act (Pike et al., 2000), thus overcoming the separation <strong>of</strong> structure from agents 46 . We<br />

follow this notion throughout our research model, assuming that the firm's managerial<br />

embedding capabilities <strong>and</strong> the actions <strong>of</strong> individual representatives <strong>of</strong> the firm work<br />

towards the collective embedding <strong>of</strong> the firm as a whole.<br />

Embedding versus embeddedness. <strong>The</strong> process <strong>of</strong> embedding <strong>and</strong> the state <strong>of</strong><br />

embeddedness are inextricably linked to context within concrete, ongoing social<br />

relations (Pike et al., 2000). Referring to a process <strong>of</strong> ‘anchoring’ firms to regional<br />

contexts, the embedding process has a distinct territorial dimension: it refers to “the<br />

processes through which subjects <strong>of</strong> economic action, while embedded in their own set<br />

<strong>of</strong> social networks, become integrated in a selected spatial object, such as the region in<br />

which the subject is located” (ibid.: 15). Embeddedness, on the other h<strong>and</strong>, relates to<br />

the structure <strong>of</strong> social relations, embodying the environment or context in which action<br />

takes place. It is “the relation <strong>of</strong> actors to others in a collectivity which affects their<br />

behaviour … [<strong>and</strong>] may bear (positive) consequences on their (economic) action”<br />

(Oinas, 1999a: 353). <strong>The</strong> scale <strong>of</strong> embeddedness is to be understood in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

interdependent layers, rather than hierarchical structures. Because embedding<br />

processes reinforce embeddedness, both terms cannot be strictly held apart in the long<br />

term, as economic actors influence, shape <strong>and</strong> affect the very economic action <strong>and</strong><br />

institutions within <strong>and</strong> through which they are reproduced <strong>and</strong> constituted. Territory<br />

therefore “is both a cause <strong>and</strong> consequence <strong>of</strong> such a process [<strong>of</strong> embedding] rather<br />

than simply a manifestation” (Pike et al., 2000). <strong>The</strong> distinction <strong>of</strong> the two terms is<br />

relevant within our research framework, since the firm itself can only undertake<br />

activities that foster its embedding process - potentially reciprocated by stakeholders'<br />

activities. <strong>The</strong>se embedding activities may result in enhanced embeddedness, <strong>and</strong><br />

possibly - as a consequence there<strong>of</strong> - in increased organisational legitimacy, which<br />

cannot be influenced in direct ways.<br />

Tie Strength. <strong>The</strong> strength <strong>of</strong> ties between two parties is defined as a “combination <strong>of</strong><br />

the amount <strong>of</strong> time, the emotional intensity, the intimacy (mutual confiding), <strong>and</strong> the<br />

reciprocal services which characterise the tie” (Granovetter, 1973: 1361). Within<br />

strategic management research the theorising <strong>of</strong> tie strength has resulted in findings<br />

which are partly contradictory (Rowley, Behrens, & Krackhardt, 2000), as different<br />

research streams promulgate for different reasons that strong <strong>and</strong> weak ties positively<br />

affect the firm's performance. <strong>The</strong> defenders <strong>of</strong> the strong tie - performance link<br />

46 This interpretation is similar to Zaheer, McEvily, & Perrone's (1998) concept <strong>of</strong> boundary-spanning<br />

individuals, see also section 4.8.5.<br />

125


126<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

stipulate that strong ties produce <strong>and</strong> are governed by relational trust, as well as norms<br />

<strong>of</strong> mutual gain <strong>and</strong> reciprocity, while they develop through repeated interactions over<br />

time (Larson, 1992). As a result <strong>of</strong> such strong ties, the firm benefits from fine-grained<br />

information exchanges <strong>and</strong> trust-based governance. Weak ties, on the other h<strong>and</strong>, are<br />

beneficial to the firm since they provide access to novel information through 'local<br />

bridges' with other parties, with whom the firm is not so familiar (Granovetter, 1973).<br />

Thus, the firm is able to access information within other networks, within which these<br />

bridging parties are connected. With regard to our research object, strong ties play an<br />

important role between the UCF <strong>and</strong> its stakeholders due to the long-term nature <strong>of</strong><br />

their relationships. As a result <strong>of</strong> incomplete contracts, strong ties <strong>and</strong> trust-based<br />

governance therefore help to overcome potential contractual or relational pitfalls <strong>and</strong><br />

reduce uncertainty <strong>and</strong> opportunism potentials, thus positively affecting the firm's<br />

performance. <strong>The</strong> development <strong>of</strong> strong ties with stakeholders therefore is an<br />

important characteristic <strong>of</strong> our local embeddedness construct.<br />

Embedded rigidity. Importantly, the marginal utility <strong>of</strong> firms' local embeddedness<br />

seems to turn negative at some point, when actors experience negative impacts from<br />

over-embeddedness. This phenomenon is related to Amin & Thrift's (1994)<br />

'institutional thickness' (cf. section 4.2). <strong>The</strong> authors claim that firms which are overly<br />

embedded in their local environment may become rigid <strong>and</strong> locked-in to their longst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

relations. As a result, the actors may be caught in behavioural patterns which<br />

inhibit learning <strong>and</strong> the exploitation <strong>of</strong> business opportunities, thus impairing the<br />

firm's competitiveness. Within our research framework we exclude the phenomenon <strong>of</strong><br />

'institutional thickness' <strong>and</strong> related negative aspects, <strong>and</strong> focus on the positive aspects<br />

<strong>of</strong> local embedding <strong>and</strong> the managerial capabilities needed to this effect.<br />

4.8.2 Organisational legitimacy<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the central claims <strong>of</strong> institutional theory is that organisations are more likely to<br />

survive, if they receive legitimacy <strong>and</strong> social support from their institutional<br />

environment, thus being accepted by the external parties within this environment.<br />

Consequently, by establishing stable institutional linkages with those external parties,<br />

the firm is able to decrease its uncertainty <strong>and</strong> the risks <strong>of</strong> organisational failure (Baum<br />

& Oliver, 1991). In other words, if firms are to “survive <strong>and</strong> thrive in their social<br />

environments … [t]hey also need social acceptability <strong>and</strong> credibility” (Scott, Ruef,<br />

Mendel, & Caronna, 2000: 237). Apart from institutional theory, this notion also<br />

attracted interest within resource dependence theory <strong>and</strong> strategic management<br />

research, which all draw from the foundational work <strong>of</strong> Weber (1978) <strong>and</strong> Parsons


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

(1960), albeit focusing on different objects <strong>of</strong> analysis. As the institutional lens on<br />

legitimacy focuses on the macro-level <strong>of</strong> legitimisation's context, the organisational<br />

lens on legitimacy explores the strategic implications <strong>of</strong> corporate social approval.<br />

Below we will briefly outline the main concepts <strong>of</strong> organisational legitimacy from<br />

both perspectives.<br />

Concepts <strong>of</strong> organisational legitimacy. Legitimacy is defined as “a generalised<br />

perception or assumption that the actions <strong>of</strong> an entity are desirable, proper, or<br />

appropriate within some socially constructed system <strong>of</strong> norms, values, beliefs, <strong>and</strong><br />

definitions” (Suchman, 1995: 574). It is a not event-specific evaluation <strong>of</strong> a subject<br />

“possessed objectively, yet created subjectively” (ibid.). On an organisational level,<br />

legitimacy means a congruence between the social values associated with or implied<br />

by the firm's activities <strong>and</strong> the norms <strong>of</strong> acceptable behaviour in the larger social<br />

system <strong>of</strong> which it forms part (Dowling & Pfeffer, 1975). Organisational legitimacy,<br />

within institutional theory, thus is shaped by three factors (Hybels, 1995; Kostova &<br />

Zaheer, 1999), namely<br />

(1) exogenously, by the environment's institutional characteristics;<br />

(2) endogenously, through the organisation's characteristics; <strong>and</strong><br />

(3) on a time-scale, through the legitimisation process by which the environment<br />

builds its perceptions <strong>of</strong> the organisation.<br />

Exogenous factors influencing the firm's organisational legitimacy include its task<br />

environment, its resource providers, its stakeholders in general, <strong>and</strong> its institutional<br />

pillars (ibid., for the latter cf. next sub-section). Endogenous factors, on the other h<strong>and</strong>,<br />

relate to the fact that the firm itself may be a collection <strong>of</strong> fragmented <strong>and</strong> varyingly<br />

interdependent <strong>and</strong> independent subunits, whose activities indirectly affect<br />

organisational legitimacy. Ultimately, the legitimisation process implicates the firm's<br />

justification “to a peer or superordinate system [<strong>of</strong>] its right to exist, that is to continue<br />

to import, transform, <strong>and</strong> export energy, material, or information” (Maurer, 1971:<br />

361). Based on these factors, <strong>and</strong> similarly to the firm's embedding processes,<br />

legitimacy is socially constructed <strong>and</strong> is the result <strong>of</strong> a reciprocal process between the<br />

firm <strong>and</strong> its environmental context. It affects not only how people act on the firm, but<br />

also how they underst<strong>and</strong> it. Legitimacy therefore acts as a dynamic constraint on<br />

organisational behaviour, changing as organisations adapt, <strong>and</strong> as the legitimacyconstituting<br />

social values change, respectively are changed (Dowling & Pfeffer, 1975).<br />

Importantly, legitimisation is not an irreversible process <strong>and</strong> firms have to persistently<br />

engage with their environment in order to maintain it (Baum & Oliver, 1991).<br />

127


128<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

From a strategic management perspective, organisational legitimacy represents a<br />

resource “that operations extract - <strong>of</strong>ten competitively - from their cultural<br />

environments <strong>and</strong> that they employ in pursuit <strong>of</strong> their goals” (Suchman, 1995: 575).<br />

Lack <strong>of</strong> legitimacy might act as a barrier to entry for firms, making them more<br />

vulnerable to claims that they are negligent, irrational or unnecessary (Meyer &<br />

Rowan, 1977). Conversely, a strong social endorsement can serve as competitive<br />

advantage: being legitimate “enables organisations to attract resources necessary for<br />

survival (e.g. scarce materials, patronage, political approval)” (Hearit, 1995: 2). Thus,<br />

organisational survival is enhanced by the organisation's legitimacy, which is why<br />

firms engage in activities to obtain <strong>and</strong> above all to maintain it. From the instrumental<br />

view taken in strategic management research, this process underlies a high level <strong>of</strong><br />

managerial control - a stance not supported by institutionalists, who rather see<br />

legitimacy as a set <strong>of</strong> constitutive beliefs. Putting legitimacy into a larger perspective,<br />

that integrates the institutionalist <strong>and</strong> the strategic notion, we conceptualise it as a<br />

construct which can only indirectly be influenced by the firm itself in making use <strong>of</strong> its<br />

embedding capabilities. Since credibility, reputation <strong>and</strong> trust are not enforceable in a<br />

structured process, the firm needs to foster them over time by means <strong>of</strong> these<br />

capabilities, working towards an alignment <strong>of</strong> the firm's perception by the public with<br />

the local system <strong>of</strong> values <strong>and</strong> beliefs. Such adaptation to implicit expectations by the<br />

environment is only possible if the local firm is sensitive to the cultural <strong>and</strong><br />

institutional disposition <strong>of</strong> its environment.<br />

Institutional pillars <strong>of</strong> organisational legitimacy. With another reference to Scott's<br />

(2001) institutional pillars, firms need to address organisational legitimacy on three<br />

dimensions:<br />

(1) regulative dimension; entails firm compliance with relevant legal or<br />

quasi-legal rules (what the firm may or must not do)<br />

(2) normative dimension; calls to moral <strong>and</strong> more internalised norms <strong>of</strong><br />

legitimacy <strong>and</strong> includes intrinsic as well as extrinsic satisfaction (what the firm<br />

should <strong>and</strong> should not do)<br />

(3) cognitive dimension; internalised, referring to a preconscious awareness<br />

level (what is or is not true, respectively what the firm can or cannot do)<br />

On the (1) regulative dimension, the mere compliance with an institutional<br />

environment's rules <strong>and</strong> regulations serves just as a firm's 'entry ticket' for being<br />

accredited with legitimacy. It constitutes the minimum a firm must do to justify its<br />

reason for existence. In comparison, embedding activities on the (2) normative <strong>and</strong> (3)


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

cognitive dimensions are differentiators towards goodwill creation, which ultimately<br />

elicit the firm's legitimacy. It is on these two dimensions, that the firm manifests its<br />

commitment to the production site <strong>and</strong> its local environment by acting beyond selfinterested<br />

(short-term) pr<strong>of</strong>it maximisation. Through activities addressing the<br />

normative dimension, <strong>and</strong> by carefully choosing their mode <strong>of</strong> implementation, the<br />

firm seeks to conform to the expectations from its local environment.<br />

Institutional exposure <strong>and</strong> organisational legitimacy. Principally, all organisations<br />

need to be endowed with a basic organisational legitimacy for their sustained<br />

livelihood. However, with reference to our research object, we reason that such<br />

legitimacy is more decisive for firms with a high institutional exposure, as is the case<br />

<strong>of</strong> UCF. <strong>The</strong>ir high visibility, the nature <strong>of</strong> their activities <strong>and</strong> their industry structure<br />

are decisive factors which result in a higher dependence on social <strong>and</strong> political support<br />

from their local environment (cf. Dowling & Pfeffer, 1975; Pfeffer, 1972). Based on<br />

the above review on the concepts <strong>of</strong> embeddedness <strong>and</strong> organisational legitimacy, as<br />

well as our empirical findings, we postulate with regard to the research object:<br />

Proposition 12<br />

<strong>The</strong> higher the firm's institutional exposure, the more its organisational embedding<br />

matters with regard to its value creation opportunities <strong>and</strong> long-term success.<br />

4.8.3 Attributes <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities<br />

In an attempt to overcome the theoretical tension between under- <strong>and</strong> over-socialised<br />

concepts <strong>of</strong> embeddedness, our proposed research framework integrates two<br />

dimensions <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities: an economic dimension which enhances<br />

organisational legitimisation through tangible contributions <strong>of</strong> the firm to its local<br />

environment, <strong>and</strong> a relational dimension, which is interdependent with - <strong>and</strong> not<br />

entirely dissociable from - the economic dimension <strong>of</strong> the firm's embedding<br />

capabilities. <strong>The</strong> economic or structural dimension pertains to the firm's rent sharing,<br />

contractual arrangements with local concession-givers, <strong>and</strong> the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> its<br />

self-governance efforts towards being a good corporate citizen. On the relational side,<br />

the firm's social embedding capabilities entail activities to build relational <strong>and</strong><br />

reputational assets <strong>and</strong> towards cultural adaptation 47 . <strong>The</strong> ensuing passages will<br />

elaborate both dimensions <strong>of</strong> 'embedding capabilities', which serve as the UCF's action<br />

47 See also Kostova & Zaheer (1999).<br />

129


130<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

parameter to mitigate its institutional exposure <strong>and</strong> the resulting effects on its value<br />

creation opportunities (cf. Figure 4-11).<br />

local exposure from<br />

location fixity (4.5 - 4.7)<br />

moderates<br />

influences<br />

value creation (4.9)<br />

embedding<br />

capabilities (4.8)<br />

structural (economic) (4.8.4)<br />

value-share remaining in region<br />

mutual lock-in with stakeholders<br />

effectiveness <strong>of</strong> self-governance<br />

relational (social) (4.8.5)<br />

local stakeholder relations<br />

reputation & trust-building<br />

cultural & institutional adaptation<br />

Figure 4-11: Attributes <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities within the research framework<br />

Acknowledging that both dimensions, the economic <strong>and</strong> the social, are “incorrigibly<br />

intertwined, unable to be separated <strong>of</strong>f from one another” (Thrift & Olds, 1996: 314),<br />

they are taken up successively for the benefit <strong>of</strong> conceptual clarity <strong>and</strong> to consequently<br />

derive apposite recommendations for value-enhancing UCF behaviour.<br />

4.8.4 Structural (economic) embedding capabilities<br />

Structural (economic) embedding capabilities include all tangible activities which<br />

manifest the firm's commitment to its location beyond symbolic actions, corporate<br />

communication <strong>and</strong> PR-functions. Such commitment, as “the state … <strong>of</strong> being<br />

obligated or emotionally impelled” 48 , includes rent-affecting firm activities, such as<br />

corporate social responsibility engagements, employee development programmes <strong>and</strong><br />

support for community education, environmental programmes, the amount <strong>of</strong> taxes<br />

paid locally 49 , <strong>and</strong> joint infrastructure development with the local administration.<br />

48<br />

Commitment. (2009). In Merriam-Webster Online Dictionary. Retrieved November 27, 2009, from:<br />

www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/commitment.<br />

49<br />

For firms, which are active across differing tax-systems <strong>and</strong> national boundaries, tax payments<br />

involve a degree <strong>of</strong> discretion, e.g. through transfer-pricing, legal <strong>and</strong> organisational structures, <strong>and</strong><br />

other means for overall tax-optimisation. It is therefore to some extent a conscious decision <strong>of</strong> the<br />

firm, to which extent it pays taxes locally, even if other tax-optimisation schemes seem more attractive<br />

in the short-term.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Viewed from an instrumental resource-dependence perspective such rent-affecting<br />

embedding activities should not just be an altruistic contribution to the greater good,<br />

but need to have an economic pay-<strong>of</strong>f in order to be justified. Economic pay-<strong>of</strong>f<br />

therefore is based on a 'quid pro quo' philosophy, whereby the firm's structural<br />

embedding efforts represent a compensation <strong>of</strong> its stakeholders for the negative<br />

externalities to which they are exposed to. It is a means to gain <strong>and</strong> preserve local<br />

support under the notions <strong>of</strong> reciprocity <strong>and</strong> legitimacy. Accordingly, stakeholders will<br />

be more inclined towards accepting negatively perceived firm-effects, if on the other<br />

h<strong>and</strong> they perceive the firm's willingness to share part <strong>of</strong> its rents. As outlined before<br />

(cf. sub-chapter 4.6.5), research has shown the validity <strong>of</strong> the reciprocity notion in<br />

human interactions under bounded rationality (Falk, Fehr, & Fischbacher, 2008; Fehr<br />

& Schmidt, 1999): “in response to friendly actions, people are frequently much nicer<br />

<strong>and</strong> much more cooperative than predicted by the self-interest model; conversely, in<br />

response to hostile actions they are frequently much more nasty <strong>and</strong> even brutal” (Fehr<br />

& Gächter, 2000: 159). Thus, the firm's compliance with normative stakeholder<br />

expectations endows it with legitimacy, <strong>and</strong> equally serves as an instrument to avert<br />

value-destroying stakeholder activities, respectively to mobilise value-enhancing<br />

stakeholder-support.<br />

In the subsequent section, we will have a closer look at how firms may enhance their<br />

structural embeddedness in order to reduce their institutional exposure, as well as to<br />

safeguard value creation opportunities. To this end, we will detail the three levers<br />

identified within our research framework:<br />

(1) Value-share remaining in region. If the notions <strong>of</strong> bounded self-interest <strong>and</strong><br />

reciprocity apply to economic actors' behaviour, firms have no choice other than to<br />

adequately compensate their environment, in order to preserve their livelihood in the<br />

long run;<br />

(2) Mutual lock-in between the firm <strong>and</strong> its main stakeholders. Due to the high<br />

commitment a UCF makes to a location by means <strong>of</strong> substantive upfront investments,<br />

the creation <strong>of</strong> mutual lock-in situations (as opposed to unilateral institutional<br />

exposure) serves the firm as a hostage to ensure its main stakeholders' sincerity in<br />

upholding their contractual commitments; in this sense an effective lock-in-creating<br />

agreement has positive implications for the firm, lowering its institutional exposure,<br />

particularly towards its public stakeholders; <strong>and</strong><br />

(3) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> (internal) governance. By establishing an effective <strong>and</strong><br />

transparent internal governance system, whose progress <strong>and</strong> results are systematically<br />

131


132<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

communicated to stakeholders, the firm signals that it is willing to acknowledge the<br />

community's needs for information <strong>and</strong> involvement. Such pro-active behaviour may<br />

particularly strengthen the firm's credibility with the regulator <strong>and</strong> other public<br />

stakeholders, in addition to creating goodwill with the remaining stakeholders.<br />

With reference to the three dimensions <strong>of</strong> organisational legitimacy (on the basis <strong>of</strong><br />

Scott, 2001), these identified levers entail obligations, choices <strong>and</strong> opportunities for<br />

the firm to enhance its structural embeddedness, as illustrated in Table 4-6.<br />

Levers <strong>of</strong><br />

structural<br />

embeddedness<br />

Value share<br />

remaining in<br />

region<br />

Mutual lock-in<br />

between the<br />

firm <strong>and</strong> its<br />

main<br />

stakeholders<br />

Effectiveness <strong>of</strong><br />

internal<br />

governance<br />

Regulative<br />

(may / must not)<br />

Taxes (obligatory<br />

minimum fraction)<br />

Labour law<br />

compliance<br />

Compliance with<br />

legal 'local content'<br />

rules<br />

Social <strong>and</strong><br />

environmental<br />

compliance<br />

Formal safeguards<br />

(contracts, hostages)<br />

Overall legal<br />

compliance<br />

Legal obligations for<br />

governance<br />

Dimensions <strong>of</strong> organisational legitimacy<br />

Normative<br />

(should / should not)<br />

Taxes (discretionary fraction)<br />

Sustainable livelihood wages<br />

& local employment<br />

<strong>Local</strong> suppliers beyond 'local<br />

content' rules<br />

CSR initiatives, such as<br />

- environmental programmes<br />

- educational initiatives<br />

- infrastructure development<br />

- sponsoring activities<br />

Informal safeguards through<br />

relationally-governed<br />

processes (trust, cooperation,<br />

flexibility, solidarity,<br />

information exchange 51 )<br />

Moral obligations<br />

Policy <strong>of</strong> ethical conduct<br />

Explicit firm values<br />

Table 4-6: Levers <strong>of</strong> structural embeddedness <strong>and</strong> organisational legitimacy<br />

Cognitive 50<br />

(can / cannot)<br />

Normative activities' fit<br />

with the implicit<br />

cultural-cognitive<br />

expectations:<br />

- which are the firm's<br />

priorities within the set<br />

<strong>of</strong> potential activities?<br />

- how are these<br />

activities aligned with<br />

(implicit) expectations<br />

<strong>of</strong> the various<br />

stakeholders?<br />

- how are these<br />

activities performed<br />

<strong>and</strong> communicated<br />

50<br />

On the cognitive dimension, the firm's structural embedding capabilities to achieve mutual lock-in<br />

are complemented by its relational embedding capabilities, which are further detailed in the next subchapter.<br />

51<br />

Cf. Poppo & Zenger (2002).


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Through the firm's activities that affect its structural embedding, it has a choice to go<br />

beyond mere regulatory compliance, as covered by the regulative dimension <strong>of</strong><br />

organisational legitimacy. In taking conscious decisions as detailed by the normative<br />

dimension in Table 4-6, it may take the right actions to live up to the explicit<br />

normative expectations <strong>and</strong> the cognitively implicit cultural <strong>and</strong> institutional<br />

expectations <strong>of</strong> its local stakeholders. Thus, the combination <strong>of</strong> its activity portfolio<br />

<strong>and</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> rent-sharing (as a demonstration <strong>of</strong> its willingness to embed itself<br />

locally), <strong>and</strong> the way it performs these activities, display its embedding capabilities.<br />

Importantly therefore, on the normative <strong>and</strong> cognitive dimension it is not only the<br />

firm's good intentions which affect its organisational legitimacy, but how well its<br />

actions overlap with the local norms <strong>and</strong> expectations. In summary, the firm's ability to<br />

identify, comprehend, <strong>and</strong> respond to the dem<strong>and</strong>s <strong>of</strong> powerful, locally relevant<br />

stakeholder groups is decisive: in order to gainfully 'do good', legitimacy-related<br />

actions must be carefully reconciled with the local institutional environment.<br />

Value-share remaining in region. From an instrumental point <strong>of</strong> view, the firm's<br />

efforts to embed locally involve investments that create intangible assets for the firm.<br />

Thus, by redistributing a part <strong>of</strong> its rents (economic or otherwise) to its stakeholders<br />

the firm intends to encourage them to engage in wealth-creating activities (Gossy,<br />

2008), or to refrain from value-destroying acts towards the firm. Likewise such rentsharing<br />

serves as a signal to the local community with regard to the firm's locational<br />

commitment <strong>and</strong> therefore represents a key component <strong>of</strong> a virtuous cycle to establish<br />

its reputation, foster legitimacy, <strong>and</strong> competitive advantage, <strong>and</strong> to ultimately create<br />

more rent (cf. Figure 4-12). <strong>The</strong> firm's instrumental embedding efforts refer to<br />

policies, programmes <strong>and</strong> processes which support its core activities, contribute to its<br />

effectiveness in accomplishing its mission <strong>and</strong> by which it yields notable business<br />

related benefits.<br />

133


134<br />

rent<br />

competitive<br />

advantage<br />

+<br />

+<br />

+<br />

+<br />

valueshareremaining<br />

in region<br />

+<br />

cooperation<br />

(due to reciprocality)<br />

+<br />

+<br />

legitimacy<br />

Figure 4-12: Virtuous cycle between value share remaining in region <strong>and</strong> rent<br />

+<br />

reputation<br />

+<br />

+<br />

trust<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

With reference to our research object, <strong>and</strong> under the behavioural assumption <strong>of</strong><br />

fairness <strong>and</strong> reciprocity, stakeholder cooperation is particularly relevant in this<br />

virtuous cycle: firms with a long-term dependence on a specific location need to pay<br />

adequate attention to the fact that continued support by their environment comes at a<br />

price. UCFs therefore might willingly accept partial appropriation <strong>of</strong> their local quasirents,<br />

if they consequently are able to avert value destruction or to create value.<br />

Although such redistribution is costly, “the primary pay<strong>of</strong>f to the firm for incurring<br />

these costs … is that it enjoys relationships with stakeholders who positively<br />

reciprocate - <strong>and</strong> that the cooperation <strong>of</strong> such stakeholders in aggregate creates rent”<br />

(Bosse et al., 2009). In an efficient market therefore firms pursue utility-maximisation,<br />

creating rent while conforming to the norms <strong>and</strong> values <strong>of</strong> society - <strong>and</strong> thus<br />

reinforcing their legitimacy on the normative <strong>and</strong> cognitive dimension.<br />

Example: 'Mi Casa' initiative <strong>of</strong> Holcim Mexico<br />

A best-practice case <strong>of</strong> economically viable rent-sharing is provided by Holcim's Mexican subsidiary<br />

Apasco, which set out to sell responsibly to the poor. Before Apasco started its initiative in 1996, many<br />

Mexicans could not afford to build their own house due to the distributional structure <strong>of</strong> the Mexican<br />

building materials sector. As a result, the country faced an annually growing housing shortage.<br />

Furthermore, owing to a lack <strong>of</strong> knowledge on building techniques, a quarter <strong>of</strong> the self-built homes<br />

had no running water or drains. Consequently, Holcim Apasco decided to start an initiative, which it<br />

called 'Mi Casa' resulting in the setting up <strong>of</strong> own distribution centres. <strong>The</strong> motivation for the<br />

initiative sprung from Apasco's conviction to have a responsibility in initiating change, while equally<br />

seeing it as a possibility for business development. In cooperation with tradespeople, local authorities,<br />

housing law experts <strong>and</strong> credit institutions, it started to sell building materials to end-consumers at<br />

+


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

affordable prices, in combination with pr<strong>of</strong>essional advice <strong>and</strong> total housing solutions. Today more<br />

than 120 st<strong>and</strong>ardised 'Mi Casa' locations ensure distribution <strong>of</strong> building materials at affordable<br />

prices, in addition to training <strong>of</strong> more than 10'000 self-builders in the necessary skills to build their<br />

home, also in remote areas <strong>of</strong> the country.<br />

While Holcim's products enable the building <strong>of</strong> private housing for the poor, the real requirement <strong>of</strong><br />

the market is not cement, but the knowledge <strong>and</strong> expertise to build safe <strong>and</strong> comfortable houses.<br />

Holcim Apasco managed to establish itself in this niche by <strong>of</strong>fering total housing solutions <strong>and</strong><br />

remodelling the local distribution structures. Thus, it is able to sell at lower prices <strong>and</strong>, at the same<br />

time, to run a pr<strong>of</strong>itable line <strong>of</strong> business. In addition its initiative helped to reinforce its legitimacy,<br />

with high br<strong>and</strong> recognition <strong>and</strong> public approval <strong>of</strong> these socially responsible activities. <strong>The</strong> resulting<br />

reputational effects have helped Holcim Apasco with new market entries, facilitating trust-building<br />

already in early phases <strong>of</strong> stakeholder relations.<br />

Degree <strong>of</strong> rent-sharing. <strong>The</strong> degree, to which the firm needs to share its rent with local<br />

stakeholders, can be assessed along the two postulated objectives <strong>of</strong> the model's action<br />

parameter: (1) the avoidance <strong>of</strong> potential damage <strong>and</strong> risk through stakeholders' power<br />

differentials <strong>and</strong> (2) the mobilisation <strong>of</strong> stakeholder support <strong>and</strong> safeguarding <strong>of</strong> future<br />

development options. With regard to the first objective, we draw on notions from the<br />

resource-based view, as well as the bargaining power perspective: Stakeholder<br />

compensation is adequate when all stakeholders receive sufficient compensation to<br />

hold them in place (i.e. pay ≥ stakeholder opportunity cost), whereas some<br />

stakeholders receive more than would be required to do so, which results in rent<br />

appropriation from the firm (C<strong>of</strong>f, 1999). <strong>The</strong>refore, the identification <strong>of</strong> the relevant<br />

stakeholders according to their threat potential, the determination <strong>of</strong> their expectations<br />

<strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> an evaluation <strong>of</strong> their alternatives for action allow the firm to<br />

approximate the opportunity cost <strong>of</strong> its stakeholders <strong>and</strong> the firm's cost to avert<br />

potential value destruction. Strategies to attain the second objective, the mobilisation<br />

<strong>of</strong> stakeholder support, equally draw on concepts <strong>of</strong> influence <strong>and</strong> power: In its efforts<br />

to safeguard future development options, the firm tries to appeal to its stakeholders'<br />

(dormant) support potential. <strong>The</strong>reby it hopes to build 'reputational stock' on which it<br />

can draw when needed. Thus, the firm aims at the creation <strong>of</strong> real options (cf. Kogut &<br />

Kulatilaka, 1994), which it 'acquires' through rent-affecting activities either directed at<br />

a bigger crowd (e.g. the local community), or at specific stakeholders (e.g. the<br />

regulator or the local administration). Examples include Corporate Social<br />

Responsibility (CSR) initiatives <strong>and</strong> efforts to decrease or compensate for the firm's<br />

externalities (e.g. through environmental programmes, CO2 compensating investments,<br />

etc.), all carefully aligned with local stakeholders' priorities <strong>and</strong> expectations. Such<br />

stocks <strong>of</strong> stakeholder loyalty may be invaluable to the UCF, particularly under<br />

135


136<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

consideration <strong>of</strong> its long planning horizon <strong>and</strong> the related uncertainties: in case <strong>of</strong><br />

unexpected crisis or emerging business development opportunities the firm thus is able<br />

to draw on its local support potential, which helps it to master the impending<br />

challenges.<br />

Overlapping objectives <strong>of</strong> structural embedding. <strong>The</strong> two objectives <strong>of</strong> structural<br />

embedding are not entirely distinct, but partially overlap <strong>and</strong> relate to each other: A<br />

stakeholder with an inherent threat-potential may as well be - or become - a supporter,<br />

as long as the firm satisfies his expectations. In other words, the firm may address a<br />

stakeholder as a 'claimant', compensating him according to his opportunity costs, <strong>and</strong><br />

simultaneously activate his support potential. Such overlaps are seen, for instance,<br />

with the local beneficiaries <strong>of</strong> airports' noise protection measures. <strong>The</strong> investment<br />

clearly is a compensation for negative externalities. However, it simultaneously might<br />

create goodwill, inducing the beneficiary to be less hostile to incremental traffic<br />

growth <strong>and</strong> future airport development plans. Another example is provided by the<br />

power industry, which frequently needs to incorporate costly requirements from<br />

environmental groups, such as fishing associations in the case <strong>of</strong> hydropower. Such<br />

measures, as for example the construction <strong>of</strong> fish ladders, compensate the associations<br />

for their opportunity costs, i.e. the pre-emption <strong>of</strong> the project. However, in addition the<br />

power provider's willingness to enter the dialogue <strong>and</strong> to invest in 'green' matters<br />

might result in a continued constructive dialogue with a win-win-orientation.<br />

Summary. In order to choose the right strategy towards structural embedding <strong>and</strong> to<br />

successfully build goodwill stocks, firms require a far-sighted management. In the<br />

short-term, the incurred cost <strong>of</strong> compensating stakeholder's opportunity cost might<br />

outweigh the perceived benefits. This is partly due to the long time-span needed to<br />

build such goodwill, <strong>and</strong> certainly due to the difficulties in quantifying the benefits,<br />

which are <strong>of</strong>ten implicit <strong>and</strong> time-displaced. In the long-term, however, sharing part <strong>of</strong><br />

the firm’s rent with the various local stakeholders secures its legitimacy <strong>and</strong> support<br />

for (or non-objection to) future development. Thus, ultimately the firm's investment to<br />

satisfy such stakeholder claims might be a fraction <strong>of</strong> the value destroyed in case <strong>of</strong><br />

lengthy legal battles <strong>and</strong> publicly organised opposition to the firm's endeavours.<br />

Example: 'Ortopolis' initiative <strong>of</strong> Holcim Brazil<br />

In a participative planning approach, Holcim Brazil launched the Ortopolis programme in 2003, with<br />

the objective <strong>of</strong> renewing the city <strong>of</strong> Barroso in a self-sustained way. After a thorough analysis <strong>of</strong> the<br />

local community's most exigent problems, projects were devised to enable sustainable socio-economic<br />

growth, <strong>and</strong> to transform the city's social, environmental, <strong>and</strong> economic sectors. In a dialogue


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

between the community, the government, <strong>and</strong> Holcim, around 2'000 people or ten percent <strong>of</strong> the local<br />

population received training to build management, leadership, <strong>and</strong> participative planning skills, as to<br />

enable them to establish <strong>and</strong> carry through the envisioned social projects. One <strong>of</strong> the key success<br />

factors for the initiative was the empowerment <strong>of</strong> the population, who consequently became an agent<br />

<strong>of</strong> its own development. By enabling such self-sustained future development, Holcim reduced the local<br />

population's dependence on it as the single biggest employer in the region. Simultaneously the firm<br />

partly benefitted from the ensuing local wealth generation in the form <strong>of</strong> local support <strong>and</strong> loyalty, as<br />

well as increased building activities.<br />

Hostages <strong>and</strong> mutual lock-in. Apart from the firm's activities to attain legitimacy <strong>and</strong><br />

goodwill, in some instances more sturdy safeguards are necessary to reduce<br />

institutional exposure <strong>and</strong> uncertainty. Although business managers <strong>of</strong>ten act on the<br />

basis <strong>of</strong> trust, the difficulty in identifying trustworthy agents forces them to structure<br />

themselves with contracts 52 <strong>and</strong> controls, serving as substitutes for trust (OE<br />

Williamson, 1975). Such governance structures form the framework within which<br />

firms negotiate, execute, <strong>and</strong> monitor exchange agreements (OE Williamson, 1985b).<br />

Particularly the existence <strong>of</strong> asset specificity influences governance structures between<br />

transaction parties, making safeguards necessary which protect against appropriation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the associated rents. Furthermore, uncertain transaction environments create greater<br />

potential for opportunistic renegotiation <strong>of</strong> the terms <strong>of</strong> a contract.<br />

Importance <strong>of</strong> mutual lock-in for UCFs. With our research object's dilemma <strong>of</strong> upfront<br />

sunk investments in specific assets, contractual safeguards become essential for the<br />

protection <strong>of</strong> its interests. Furthermore, UCFs employ alternative modes <strong>of</strong> governance<br />

with their key stakeholders with whom they have commercial <strong>and</strong> legal links. As<br />

exchange hazards rise (i.e. exposure through dependence, measurement problems,<br />

changing conditions over time, ill-defined property rights, <strong>and</strong> weaknesses in the<br />

institutional environment), so must the UCF's contractual safeguards, whose neglect<br />

may otherwise lead to a lock-in situation after the firm has incurred its sunk costs. If a<br />

party becomes 'locked-in' in a bilateral exchange, the nature <strong>of</strong> the interaction<br />

transforms from voluntary exchange to a comm<strong>and</strong> structure, “within which one party<br />

lacks the ability to retaliate” (Wathne & Heide, 2000: 39). <strong>The</strong> locked-in player<br />

thereby is forced to tolerate opportunistic behaviour because he cannot terminate the<br />

relationship without incurring economic losses. Underpinned by Buchanan's claim that<br />

“mutuality <strong>of</strong> advantage from voluntary exchange is ... the most fundamental <strong>of</strong> all<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ings in economics” (Buchanan, 2001: 29), it must therefore be the firm's<br />

52 Contracts, in this context, are understood in their more restrictive form, defined as "legally binding<br />

promises" (McNeil, 1974: 693).<br />

137


138<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

objective to pre-empt a unilateral lock-in. By creating a (more or less balanced) mutual<br />

dependence or lock-in situation, the UCF may have a means to promote the other<br />

party's commitment <strong>and</strong> mediate the effects <strong>of</strong> specific investments on relationship<br />

outcomes (D. Davis & Mentzer, 2008).<br />

Relations with public stakeholders. In its long-term relations with third parties which<br />

are critical to its functioning, the firm relies on protective mechanisms that shield it<br />

from the incompleteness <strong>of</strong> contracts <strong>and</strong> any resulting exposure. With reference to the<br />

nature <strong>of</strong> UCF, such protective mechanisms are particularly crucial in the firm's<br />

relations with its public stakeholders, due to the inherent power differential between<br />

the parties. Contractual firm - government relationships may be compared to private<br />

economy relationships, ins<strong>of</strong>ar as both parties assume contractual obligations.<br />

However, as has been outlined before (cf. section 'Public shareholder', pp. 107), when<br />

the government itself is party to the contract (e.g. as a giver <strong>of</strong> concession or orderer <strong>of</strong><br />

a 'service public'), its monopoly over the enforcement <strong>of</strong> property rights might come<br />

into conflict with its contractual commitments, thus tempting it to renege ex post.<br />

Relations with public stakeholders that extend over long periods therefore are rife with<br />

uncertainty, since - depending on the degree <strong>of</strong> political stability - the firm cannot be<br />

sure on the direction <strong>and</strong> content <strong>of</strong> government policies in the future. <strong>The</strong>re might be<br />

changes in the political agenda, regulatory developments, or - in institutional<br />

environments with low legal certainty - incentives for predatory government behaviour<br />

<strong>and</strong> conflicting public agents' private agendas 53 .<br />

Governance mechanisms in firm-government relationships. <strong>The</strong>refore, in conjunction<br />

with irreversible, specialised investments the firm needs to consider a number <strong>of</strong><br />

protective mechanisms, based on trust, coercion, <strong>and</strong> incentives as relevant dimensions<br />

<strong>of</strong> governance. To protect itself, the firm might rely on (1) third party enforcement,<br />

whereby the firm may draw on the support <strong>of</strong> an additional party with the ability <strong>and</strong><br />

the incentive to punish the government, if the firm's contractually guaranteed interests<br />

are at stake. Furthermore, the firm may aim at (2) interest alignment through formal<br />

safeguards, thus diminishing the incentives for defection <strong>and</strong> breach <strong>of</strong> contract.<br />

Ultimately it may make use <strong>of</strong> (3) relational contracts <strong>and</strong> goal convergence through<br />

informal safeguards, thus deliberately employing socialisation tactics in order to<br />

mitigate the risks <strong>of</strong> incomplete contracts <strong>and</strong> ex-post opportunism. <strong>The</strong> second <strong>and</strong><br />

53 Ramamurti (2003) subsumes three explanations for ex-post government reneging: (1) economic<br />

uncertainty, making a renegotiation necessary, (2) the logic <strong>of</strong> obsolescing bargain, which makes deals<br />

appear less attractive ex-post <strong>and</strong> (3) political change.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

third mechanisms are self-enforcing, referred to as private ordering. Both intend “to<br />

realign incentives <strong>and</strong> embed transactions in more protective governance structures [to<br />

mitigate] the contractual problems that would otherwise arise” (OE Williamson, 2002:<br />

438). Figure 4-13 illustrates the three principal forms <strong>of</strong> governance on the basis <strong>of</strong><br />

Dyer <strong>and</strong> Singh (1998).<br />

third party<br />

enforcement<br />

governance<br />

mechanisms<br />

Figure 4-13: Principal forms <strong>of</strong> governance<br />

private ordering<br />

(self-enforcement)<br />

formal safeguards [informal safeguards*]<br />

* cf. section 4.8.5 on relational<br />

(social) embedding capabilities<br />

All three strategies serve as a means to mitigate the risk <strong>of</strong> the other party's defection.<br />

While the first two build on rather coercive means <strong>and</strong> economic reasoning to ensure<br />

protection, the third strategy relates to a more socialised view <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

transactions, taking into consideration the actor's relational embeddedness in order to<br />

mitigate the risks <strong>of</strong> opportunism. <strong>The</strong> effective combination <strong>of</strong> strategies, however,<br />

depends on the institutional environment, to which the governance structure 54 has to be<br />

aligned.<br />

(1) Third party enforcement. In finding a third party whose interests <strong>and</strong> rents are<br />

linked with the firm's interests, <strong>and</strong> who has the capacity to monitor <strong>and</strong> punish the<br />

government in case <strong>of</strong> contract breach, the government's ability <strong>and</strong> incentive to<br />

renege may be diminished. In order to be effective, the third party ideally is<br />

institutionalised, in the sense that it is more than a group <strong>of</strong> individuals <strong>and</strong> will exist<br />

beyond the lifespan <strong>of</strong> its individual members. Furthermore, it should be directly<br />

linked to the decision makers <strong>of</strong> the government which is contractual party to the firm.<br />

Such third parties, for instance, may be foreign states or domestic groups, which have<br />

the capacity to threaten the government (Haber, Maurer, & Razo, 2003). Third party<br />

nations may become involved through ownership or investment interests that citizens<br />

54 A governance structure is understood as "a shorth<strong>and</strong> expression for the institutional framework in<br />

which contracts are initiated, negotiated, monitored, adapted, enforced, <strong>and</strong> terminated" (Palay, 1984<br />

cited in: Ménard, 2004: 368).<br />

139


140<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

or businesses <strong>of</strong> their nationality have in the firm, <strong>and</strong> which it needs to protect. Such<br />

third party enforcement may be illustrated by the case <strong>of</strong> Bangalore International<br />

Airport (BIAL), <strong>of</strong> which the German multinational Siemens is the biggest<br />

shareholder. When the rent streams <strong>of</strong> BIAL were significantly impacted by the Indian<br />

government's delay in approval <strong>of</strong> a regulated fee 55 to which BIAL had a right, the<br />

issue was taken up to a political level, in order to speed up the process. <strong>The</strong><br />

government <strong>of</strong> Germany temporarily took over the role <strong>of</strong> a third party enforcer <strong>and</strong><br />

successfully sped up the approval process. <strong>The</strong> second type <strong>of</strong> third party enforcers<br />

refers to groups, such as NGOs <strong>and</strong> multilateral agencies - e.g. the International<br />

Finance Corporation as a member <strong>of</strong> the World Bank Group - which are able to<br />

credibly threaten the government, <strong>and</strong> whose rents are directly related to the asset<br />

holder's economic activities. Such enforcement is illustrated by the airport industry,<br />

which may rely on a number <strong>of</strong> domestic stakeholders, on whom its activities has a<br />

direct or indirect economic impact. If a government therefore intends to limit an<br />

airport's activities (e.g. due to higher prioritisation <strong>of</strong> other public policy objectives),<br />

consequently reducing the location's international connectivity, the regional tourism<br />

<strong>and</strong> trade associations would effectively protest against such intentions. While the<br />

trade associations would stress the threat <strong>of</strong> migrating international businesses, the<br />

tourism industry would exert pressure by pointing to an expected decline in tourism<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> knock-on effects on the national economy.<br />

(2) Interest alignment through formal safeguards. As another means to protect itself<br />

against institutional exposure, the firm may create self-enforcing agreements which<br />

entail “an incentive structure that makes the long-term gains from cooperative<br />

behaviour exceed the short-term pay<strong>of</strong>f from opportunism” (Wathne & Heide, 2000:<br />

44). Usually self-enforcing agreements remain in force as long as each party considers<br />

itself to be better <strong>of</strong>f by continuing rather than by ending the agreement. <strong>The</strong>y may be<br />

<strong>of</strong> formal or informal nature, the latter <strong>of</strong> which will be discussed in the subsequent<br />

paragraph. Formal safeguards relate to financial <strong>and</strong> investment hostages (Dyer, 1996)<br />

in the form <strong>of</strong> investments in specific assets. With the aim to control opportunism, they<br />

align incentives (Benjamin Klein, 1980) <strong>and</strong> ensure credible commitments, with which<br />

55 When India privatised its first airports in 2008, there was a political controversy on the financing <strong>of</strong><br />

these airports <strong>and</strong> their future investment needs. <strong>The</strong> State had previously granted to the private<br />

investors a User Development Fee (UDF), whose amount would be determined by a body <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Ministry <strong>of</strong> Civil Aviation on the basis <strong>of</strong> the airports' audited cost. <strong>The</strong> public discussion on the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> such fees in combination with the economic slowdown, however, led the government<br />

to delay its introduction. Today, the UDF is an accepted means to ensure the refinancing <strong>of</strong> airports.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

the parties strengthen their relationship <strong>and</strong> promote exchange through reciprocal<br />

exposure (OE Williamson, 1983).<br />

In view <strong>of</strong> the government's monopoly <strong>of</strong> power, the firm may choose between two<br />

strategies <strong>of</strong> formal safeguards. On one h<strong>and</strong>, it may dem<strong>and</strong> ex-ante credible<br />

commitments by devising a relationship <strong>of</strong> mutual reliance with the government. Such<br />

mutuality may result, for instance, from making the government a partial shareholder,<br />

from securing upfront financial support (e.g. through cash grants or loans or in-kind<br />

contributions) <strong>and</strong> guarantees, or by clearly defining the contractual conditions, when<br />

the firm is allowed to terminate the contract, exit the venture, <strong>and</strong> to claim<br />

compensation from the state 56 . Alternatively, the firm may choose to pay a price<br />

premium in order to increase the attractiveness <strong>of</strong> contract adherence. For instance, the<br />

UCF could pay a recurrent concession fee above the economically justified level, in<br />

order to secure a sustained buy-in from the government. Importantly, the following<br />

conditions increase the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> self-enforcing agreements:<br />

- open-ended business relations: formal self-enforcement mechanisms require<br />

inter-party relations without a termination date, since in transaction sequences<br />

with a definite known last element the parties will most probably behave<br />

opportunistically (Telser, 1980);<br />

- long-term business relations: the gains <strong>of</strong> adhering to a self-enforcing<br />

agreement are higher, the longer the relation holds; <strong>and</strong><br />

- stable business environment: the probability for adherence is higher in an<br />

environment with low uncertainty, since the latter increases the chances that<br />

one party behaves opportunistically.<br />

Compared to third-party enforcement <strong>of</strong> agreements, the self-regulated governance<br />

results in lower monitoring <strong>and</strong> transaction costs, since self-enforcement also requires<br />

self-monitoring, <strong>and</strong> contracting costs can be avoided (Dyer & Singh, 1998).<br />

(3) Relational contracts - goal convergence through informal safeguards. <strong>The</strong><br />

discussed inter-organisational, respectively firm - government exchanges typically<br />

involve long-term relationships, which are embedded in their local environment <strong>and</strong><br />

characterised by repeated interactions. In the absence <strong>of</strong> trust such interactions are<br />

regulated by rules <strong>and</strong> compliance, which involve the costly specification, negotiation,<br />

56 Most governments, however, while wanting the UCF to realise the costly infrastructure project, will<br />

wish to distance themselves from the related financial burden <strong>and</strong> risks. Indeed, a major reason for a<br />

government to issue concessions for such long-term ventures is to pass on the cost <strong>and</strong> burden <strong>of</strong><br />

project development.<br />

141


142<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

management <strong>and</strong> monitoring <strong>of</strong> contracts. In contrast, relationally-governed exchanges<br />

enforce obligations, promises, <strong>and</strong> expectations “through social processes that promote<br />

norms <strong>of</strong> flexibility, solidarity <strong>and</strong> information exchange” (Poppo & Zenger, 2002:<br />

710). Such relationally-governed interaction involves informal self-enforcing<br />

agreements, based on the existence <strong>of</strong> trust between the parties, <strong>and</strong> their reputation.<br />

<strong>The</strong>reby, a joint underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> informal norms evolves into relational governance,<br />

which mitigates precisely those risks that formal contracts try to control. Since the<br />

involved parties mutually underst<strong>and</strong> their relations to be long-term, there are<br />

considerable incentives to invest in specific assets, protected by mutually-imposed<br />

costs <strong>of</strong> termination. From an economic point <strong>of</strong> view, the behaviour can be compared<br />

to infinite repeated interactions in game-theory, emphasising the calculative element <strong>of</strong><br />

the interactions. Arguing from an opposite angle, economic sociology stresses the<br />

element <strong>of</strong> trust <strong>and</strong> the relational advantages emerging from the interactions, e.g. in<br />

the form <strong>of</strong> ties which commit the parties to the contract. Ultimately, however, both<br />

perspectives agree that trustworthy behaviour <strong>and</strong> good reputations are rewarded. On<br />

the other h<strong>and</strong>, breach <strong>of</strong> trust negatively affects reputation, which consequently is<br />

punished by potential transaction partners (see also the discussion <strong>of</strong> trust <strong>and</strong><br />

reputation, section 4.8.5).<br />

In their analysis <strong>of</strong> the substitutability <strong>of</strong> formal contracts <strong>and</strong> informal relational<br />

governance, Poppo <strong>and</strong> Zenger (2002) conclude, that firms should aim at<br />

complementarily combining both approaches to optimally safeguard their interests. To<br />

this effect, the formal contract should contain disincentives for cheating by defining<br />

explicit penalties. Thus, the parties may overcome the limits <strong>of</strong> relational governance,<br />

while reinforcing their incentives to invest in their relationship. In a combined<br />

approach, therefore, high asset specificity <strong>of</strong> the firm's assets tends to increase the<br />

complexity <strong>of</strong> formal contracts, while high uncertainty leads to the development <strong>of</strong><br />

greater levels <strong>of</strong> relational norms <strong>and</strong> governance (Crocker & Masten, 1991), which<br />

compensate for the adaptive limits <strong>of</strong> formal contracts. Pertaining to firm-government<br />

relations, it is evident, that both elements are crucial for the protection <strong>of</strong> the firm's<br />

interests: Whereas the formal contractual arrangement <strong>of</strong>fers some enforceability in<br />

the longer term, the relational dimension (depending on the institutional <strong>and</strong> cultural<br />

setting <strong>of</strong> the host country) protects the firm in the short-term from opportunistic<br />

behaviour throughout election cycles.<br />

Summary. Overall, in order to reduce its institutional exposure <strong>and</strong> the incentives for<br />

opportunism <strong>and</strong> reneging, the firm needs credible commitments from its key<br />

stakeholders. Such commitments are particularly valuable with regard to those


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

stakeholders, whose relation with the firm is characterised by asset specificity.<br />

Pertaining to the UCF this applies foremost to its public stakeholders, such as<br />

governments, the local administration <strong>and</strong> the regulator. <strong>The</strong> ideal mix between formal<br />

credible commitments (contracts) <strong>and</strong> informal ones (relational governance) depends<br />

on the firm's local institutional <strong>and</strong> cultural context.<br />

Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> self-monitoring <strong>and</strong> governance. In their efforts to advance<br />

structural embedding, firms have an additional opportunity for the creation <strong>of</strong> goodwill<br />

<strong>and</strong> legitimacy: social <strong>and</strong> environmental accounting. By voluntarily engaging in selfmonitoring,<br />

such as the tracking <strong>of</strong> one's negative externalities, <strong>and</strong> the subsequent<br />

publication <strong>of</strong> results to stakeholders with a perceived right-to-information (Donaldson<br />

& Preston, 1995), a genuine commitment to sustainability <strong>and</strong> transparency is<br />

signalled to the local environment. <strong>The</strong> motivations <strong>of</strong> management, to proactively go<br />

to such lengths, may stem from a perceived aggregate benefit <strong>of</strong> such activities<br />

(instrumental motivation), or from a belief that they have an accountability or<br />

responsibility to do so (normative obligation). Equally, firm's activities to this effect<br />

may be reactive, for example as a response to external pressure, peer pressure through<br />

emerging industry st<strong>and</strong>ards, or to negative media coverage - in short, to avert<br />

negative consequences <strong>and</strong> loss <strong>of</strong> legitimacy. Mostly, various interdependent reasons<br />

affect the firm's approach to self-governance, combining normative ethical <strong>and</strong><br />

instrumental strategic considerations. Thus, it is able to reinforce its social contract<br />

with its stakeholders, which is based on the foundation <strong>of</strong> delivering some socially<br />

desirable ends to society in general, <strong>and</strong> the distribution <strong>of</strong> economic, social, or<br />

political benefits to those stakeholders, from whom the firm derives its power<br />

(Shocker & Sethi, 1973, as cited in Deegan, 2002: 296). Being fully aware <strong>of</strong> the<br />

normative obligations <strong>and</strong> the related economic advantages <strong>of</strong> such voluntary reporting<br />

activities, as well as its inward effects on the organisation, Holcim for example states:<br />

<strong>The</strong> value <strong>of</strong> sustainability reporting to an organisation lies not in the outward<br />

facing aspects – the report itself - but rather in the inward facing processes that<br />

robust reporting requires. <strong>The</strong> discipline <strong>of</strong> setting <strong>and</strong> monitoring targets focuses<br />

the organisation to allocate resources in meaningful areas <strong>and</strong> ensures that<br />

effective structures are in place to drive the triple bottom line 57 agenda. (HGRS -<br />

CSR/SD Coordination, 2008: 14)<br />

57 I.e. the balancing <strong>of</strong> social, environmental <strong>and</strong> economic performance.<br />

143


144<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Through its focus on the triple bottom line, the company strategically anchors the<br />

obligation to balance social, environmental <strong>and</strong> economic performance, which<br />

reinforces the efforts towards its local embedding <strong>and</strong> legitimisation.<br />

Example: Self-monitoring <strong>and</strong> information disclosure at Holcim's Albox Plant, Spain<br />

In 2003, Holcim Spain opened a waste pre-treatment platform in the town <strong>of</strong> Albox. <strong>The</strong> project was<br />

met by the local population with distrust <strong>and</strong> opposition, due to uncertainties related to waste co-<br />

processing. In its efforts to win the critical stakeholders for the project, Holcim commissioned the<br />

German 'Gesellschaft für Technische Zusammenarbeit GmbH' (GTZ) as an independent third party, to<br />

assure the innocuousness <strong>and</strong> safety <strong>of</strong> the plant operation. Furthermore, KPMG provided<br />

independent assurance on CO2 emissions in 2004 <strong>and</strong> 2005. On the basis <strong>of</strong> recommendations from<br />

the Community Advisory Panel CAP, which it established early on (cf. example p.175), Holcim<br />

decided to allow public access to all safety- <strong>and</strong> environment-related company documents. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

documents included impact assessments, emissions data, safety reports <strong>and</strong> hazardous waste<br />

declarations. <strong>The</strong> length to which Holcim went, in order to ensure transparency finally won it the<br />

approval <strong>of</strong> the local stakeholders <strong>and</strong> allowed it to continue its operation in a constructive way.<br />

Do good <strong>and</strong> let the world know about it. If, <strong>and</strong> to which extent a firm's operation is<br />

in accordance with the social contract, is subject to individual <strong>and</strong> subjective<br />

assessment, since the firm's legitimacy derives from individual stakeholders'<br />

perceptions. However, as social disclosure forms part <strong>of</strong> the dialogue between the<br />

company <strong>and</strong> its stakeholders, firms may engage in corporate social reporting as a<br />

means to positively affect those public perceptions <strong>and</strong> to negotiate firm-stakeholder<br />

relationships. If the firm is sincere in its embedding <strong>and</strong> legitimisation efforts, such<br />

reporting activities are valuable all the more, because the firm's efforts influence<br />

stakeholder perceptions solely, if they are effectively communicated. Importantly<br />

therefore, neither communication without sincerity in efforts, nor endeavours towards<br />

sustainability <strong>and</strong> continuous improvement without telling the public, will improve<br />

perceived legitimacy <strong>of</strong> the firm in the long term.<br />

<strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> self-governance efforts for UCF. If the firm decides to monitor its key<br />

indicators for a socially responsible demeanour <strong>and</strong> to make (part <strong>of</strong>) those data<br />

transparent to the public, it may expect a number <strong>of</strong> positive effects. As Holcim<br />

continues in its statement on the value <strong>of</strong> sustainability reporting:<br />

Sustainability reporting has the capacity to add value to an organisation for a<br />

variety <strong>of</strong> stakeholders. Investors prefer to invest in companies that demonstrate<br />

through effective reporting that they operate responsibly, employees prefer to work<br />

for such companies <strong>and</strong> civil society <strong>and</strong> governments tend to trust those<br />

organisations more. (HGRS - CSR/SD Coordination, 2008: 14)


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Thus, self-governance efforts may facilitate the firm's access to capital markets,<br />

preclude restrictive government action, positively affect public opinion, <strong>and</strong> - as a<br />

result - increase the firm's competitive position compared to its industry rivals. For the<br />

highly regulated UCF, such signalling <strong>of</strong> 'good corporate citizenship' might also<br />

alleviate the firm from significant administrative burdens. Under assumption <strong>of</strong><br />

behavioural reciprocity, the firm's commendable comportment with regard to<br />

transparency <strong>and</strong> pro-active information helps the various regulatory bodies to be<br />

reassured on its good intentions. Consequently, the latter are able to take a constructive<br />

regulatory approach, for instance by engaging in a forward-looking dialogue with the<br />

firm instead <strong>of</strong> using sovereign coercion, or by focusing their resources on less<br />

exemplary firms. In such a trust-based environment, the firm may also take some<br />

influence on future regulatory agendas by proactively setting best practice st<strong>and</strong>ards,<br />

beyond the regulatory minimum, thus helping the regulator to find a balanced<br />

approach to emerging issues. By means <strong>of</strong> such self-governing engagements, the firm<br />

therefore exploits a money-saving potential in the form <strong>of</strong> lesser administrative <strong>and</strong><br />

legal procedures, avoidance <strong>of</strong> costly law-suits or ad-hoc regulatory interference. In<br />

addition, the freed up managerial capacity usually bound by regulatory issues allow<br />

the firm to re-focus on its strategic objectives <strong>and</strong> to engage in further legitimacybuilding<br />

activities.<br />

Influence <strong>of</strong> local institutional set-up. In addition to the firm's incentives from these<br />

benefits, a country's legal set-up with regard to citizens' rights to information may<br />

further increase the motivation towards enhanced self-governance activities. Some<br />

empirical evidence suggests that “government statutes are most effective in facilitating<br />

socially responsible corporate environmental behaviour if they afford citizens access to<br />

information about toxic emissions, legal st<strong>and</strong>ing in court to sue suspected polluters,<br />

<strong>and</strong> sufficient resources to support both <strong>of</strong> these activities” (J. Campbell, 2007: 955).<br />

Thus, the state plays an important role in the self-regulation incentives <strong>of</strong> firms<br />

(Karkkainen, Fung, & Sabel, 2000; Mitchell et al., 1997), since it affects their<br />

institutional exposure in the form <strong>of</strong> (theoretical) power <strong>of</strong> stakeholders to follow<br />

through with the monitoring <strong>of</strong> corporate performance. As a consequence far-sighted<br />

firms recognise their chance to pre-empt regulatory interference by proactively<br />

engaging in self-governance, rather than leaving it to state regulation to set further<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ards over which they would have little control.<br />

Firm credibility <strong>and</strong> corporate governance. Although firms' voluntary self-monitoring<br />

<strong>and</strong> reporting have gained in popularity, they do not always result in noticeable<br />

impacts on public trust. One possible explanation is that voluntary firm disclosures are<br />

145


146<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

received with hesitance due to a lack <strong>of</strong> confidence in the reported data <strong>and</strong> the<br />

reporting firm's sincerity (D<strong>and</strong>o & Swift, 2003). In order to overcome this credibility<br />

gap <strong>and</strong> to prove the honesty behind their efforts, firms therefore need to demonstrate<br />

overall good corporate governance, understood as the system by which companies are<br />

directed <strong>and</strong> controlled (Cadbury, 1992). Corporate governance is based on two key<br />

elements, power (particularly on the allocation <strong>of</strong> corporate funds) <strong>and</strong> responsibility<br />

(for corporate performance, proper corporate conduct, etc.). It therefore has significant<br />

impact on firms' value creation <strong>and</strong> rent distribution, but also on its culture, as well as<br />

its attitude <strong>and</strong> sense <strong>of</strong> responsibility towards its stakeholders. To instil public trust in<br />

its corporate governance system (<strong>and</strong> consequently in its voluntarily disclosed<br />

information) the firm may take a number <strong>of</strong> measures: (1) Instalment <strong>of</strong> a CSR<br />

Steering Committee: as part <strong>of</strong> the firm's internal governance mechanisms CSR<br />

Steering Committees have become popular over the past decade, composed <strong>of</strong> senior<br />

executives <strong>and</strong> reporting to the board <strong>of</strong> directors (Cooper & Owen, 2007). Social <strong>and</strong><br />

environmental issues are thus brought up to the board's attention by top-class<br />

managers, who lend the issues more weight <strong>and</strong> keep vigil on the firm's h<strong>and</strong>ling<br />

there<strong>of</strong>. (2) Third party assurance: another expedient is the commissioning <strong>of</strong><br />

independent third party assurance, as a guarantor to the public that monitoring-data or<br />

the information in a report is true <strong>and</strong> fair on the basis <strong>of</strong> the third party's impartiality.<br />

To improve the firm's credibility the independent auditor proceeds in accordance with<br />

accepted st<strong>and</strong>ards, such as the Stakeholder Engagement St<strong>and</strong>ard (AA1000SES) 58 or<br />

the International St<strong>and</strong>ard on Assurance Engagements (ISAE 3000) 59 . Most<br />

importantly, the third party's favourable assessment <strong>of</strong> follow-up actions to prior<br />

recommendations generally strengthens a firm's public st<strong>and</strong>ing. (3) External board<br />

members: the appointment <strong>of</strong> external board members, i.e. the co-optation <strong>of</strong> political<br />

leaders or other persons <strong>of</strong> legitimate status, can increase the firm's credibility<br />

(Dowling & Pfeffer, 1975). (4) Good corporate citizenship: finally, the fourth<br />

58<br />

<strong>The</strong> AAI1000 st<strong>and</strong>ard has been developed by AccountAbility in 1999, as principles for sustainable<br />

development with the objective to develop a widely accepted st<strong>and</strong>ard for CSR reporting. In its core, it<br />

calls on the firms' inclusivity, i.e. integrating stakeholders in the h<strong>and</strong>ling <strong>of</strong> sustainability issues;<br />

materiality; completeness; <strong>and</strong> responsiveness in CSR reporting.<br />

59<br />

<strong>The</strong> ISAE's objective is to provide a basic framework for large scale audits concerned with nonfinancial<br />

data process monitoring. <strong>The</strong>se types <strong>of</strong> audits include environmental, social <strong>and</strong><br />

sustainability reports; auditing <strong>of</strong> information systems, internal control, <strong>and</strong> corporate governance<br />

processes; <strong>and</strong> compliance audits for grant conditions, contracts <strong>and</strong> regulations. In 2003, the st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

was upgraded to ISAE 3000 in order to further address ethical requirements; quality control;<br />

engagement acceptance; planning; expert materials; obtaining evidence; documentation; <strong>and</strong> preparing<br />

assurance reports.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

credibility-gauging factor is not part <strong>of</strong> the firm's governance system, but rather the<br />

result <strong>of</strong> good corporate citizenship. <strong>The</strong> attestation <strong>of</strong> a firm's sincerity by public<br />

awards <strong>and</strong> labels, as for example the Dow Jones Sustainability Index 60 or the ACCA<br />

Environmental Reporting Awards 61 , possess a significant signalling function. Such<br />

commendation from an independent third party lend the firm high credibility, because<br />

they are the result <strong>of</strong> the firm's self-governance efforts, <strong>and</strong> the evaluation process can<br />

hardly be directly influenced by the firm. Research has brought forward abundant<br />

literature on corporate governance <strong>and</strong> corporate social responsibility, whose review<br />

<strong>and</strong> assessment would exceed the scope <strong>of</strong> the present research. Instead, we would like<br />

to refer to two excellent reviews by Becht, Bolton, <strong>and</strong> Röell (2007) on corporate<br />

governance literature <strong>and</strong> by Garriga <strong>and</strong> Melé (2004) on CSR.<br />

Example: Credible sustainability - Holcim's commitment to CSR<br />

One <strong>of</strong> Holcim's earliest efforts to embed CSR in its firm philosophy was the initiation <strong>of</strong> the Cement<br />

Sustainability Initiative (CSI) 62 in 1999, together with two industry peers. Since then Holcim adopts<br />

the priorities set by the CSI through its group-wide sustainable development (SD) initiative. In this<br />

initiative the firm sets st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>and</strong> guidelines, <strong>and</strong> advances the implementation <strong>of</strong> best practices in<br />

order to reduce its ecological footprint. As a part <strong>of</strong> its commitment, Holcim publishes sustainability<br />

reports, statistics on its CO2 emissions, <strong>and</strong> a range <strong>of</strong> other reports on its activities - on a global <strong>and</strong><br />

a local level. <strong>The</strong> credibility <strong>of</strong> these publications is strengthened by their accreditation through<br />

reputable auditing firms.<br />

Summary. If the firm manages to convey to its stakeholders credibility <strong>and</strong> corrective<br />

actions in its self-regulation efforts, it will be able to build trust <strong>and</strong> increase its public<br />

approval. As a result, the firm may benefit from the formation <strong>of</strong> relational rents <strong>and</strong><br />

isolating mechanisms against competition, ultimately leading to sustainable value<br />

creation. <strong>The</strong>refore, by engaging in self-monitoring <strong>and</strong> a pro-active information<br />

60 Launched in 1999, the Dow Jones Sustainability Index (DJSI) series provided the first global<br />

sustainability benchmarks worldwide. <strong>The</strong> DJSI indices include leading companies worldwide <strong>and</strong><br />

across all industries with regard to long-term economic, environmental <strong>and</strong> social criteria.<br />

Components are selected according to a systematic corporate sustainability assessment that identifies<br />

the sustainability leaders in each <strong>of</strong> 57 industry groups.<br />

61<br />

<strong>The</strong> ACCA awards scheme has been launched in 1991, with the objective to publicise the issue <strong>of</strong><br />

corporate environmental, social <strong>and</strong> sustainability reporting, <strong>and</strong> holding up pressure for reporting<br />

reform by publishing annual reports <strong>of</strong> the panel <strong>of</strong> judges.<br />

62<br />

CSI was set up as a member-sponsored program <strong>of</strong> the World Business Council for Sustainable<br />

Development (WBCSD), a coalition <strong>of</strong> 175 international companies united by a shared commitment to<br />

sustainable development via the three pillars <strong>of</strong> economic growth, ecological balance <strong>and</strong> social<br />

progress.<br />

147


148<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

policy, what looks like a cost factor at first sight, might turn into a net-economising<br />

activity portfolio from an overall firm-perspective.<br />

4.8.5 Relational (social) embedding capabilities<br />

While the structural (economic) <strong>and</strong> the relational (social) dimensions <strong>of</strong> embedding<br />

are distinct, they are not completely exclusive. In the conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> the firm's<br />

structural embedding capabilities, it has become evident that the boundaries between<br />

the two remain vague, mainly because all elements <strong>of</strong> economic embeddedness also<br />

have an inherent social component. Through a combination <strong>of</strong> the firm's structural <strong>and</strong><br />

relational embedding capabilities, it is able to create safety nets to limit the downside<br />

risks <strong>of</strong> its institutional exposure, as well as opportunity platforms creating options for<br />

future courses <strong>of</strong> action (Fombrun, Gardberg, & Barnett, 2000). Thus, it increases its<br />

organisational legitimacy, whose effects are summarised by Boddewyn & Brewer<br />

(1994: 134):<br />

[Legitimacy] is a political resource that firms want to secure because it facilitates<br />

the acquisition <strong>of</strong> economic resources in their value- added chains as well as access<br />

to policy makers, influence in public policy making, <strong>and</strong> reduction in opposition<br />

from other stakeholders.<br />

<strong>The</strong> following sub-chapter will shift focus towards assessing the characteristics <strong>of</strong><br />

legitimacy-endowing capabilities from a relational perspective. <strong>The</strong>se capabilities<br />

essentially are composed <strong>of</strong> three elements:<br />

(1) Building local stakeholder relations: Through cultivation <strong>of</strong> local<br />

stakeholder relations the firm is able to establish trust (see also subsequent<br />

point) <strong>and</strong> strong relational ties. Constructive relationships with the firm's<br />

local stakeholders activate their reciprocal behaviour, whereby the<br />

accumulated relational capital may be used to enhance the firm's options,<br />

reduce its risks <strong>and</strong> consequently to create value.<br />

(2) Reputation- <strong>and</strong> trust-building: By being responsive to stakeholders'<br />

expectations, the firm may influence the external perception <strong>of</strong> itself, i.e. the<br />

“cognitive representation <strong>of</strong> [its] actions <strong>and</strong> results that crystallizes the<br />

firm's ability to deliver valued outcomes to its stakeholders” (Fombrun et al.,<br />

2000: 87). By signalling thus to its stakeholders, what behaviour they may<br />

expect from the firm in the future, it builds reputational capital <strong>and</strong> generates<br />

“reputational gains that improve a company's ability to attract resources,<br />

enhance its performance, <strong>and</strong> build competitive advantage” (ibid.2000: 85).


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Desirable reputational characteristics include, among others, being perceived<br />

as trustworthy, reliable, transparent, <strong>and</strong> honest.<br />

Similarly, through repeated interaction the firm establishes trust with its<br />

stakeholders, which facilitates their exchange <strong>of</strong> resources <strong>and</strong> information.<br />

A trusting relationship thus acts as a unique governance mechanism: Mutual<br />

trust with regard to capabilities <strong>and</strong> competencies, as well as behaviour,<br />

reduces uncertainty <strong>and</strong> consequently transaction costs in the parties'<br />

exchanges, thereby creating value for the firm.<br />

Figure 4-14 illustrates the links between the first two relational embedding capabilities<br />

<strong>and</strong> how they relate to value creation.<br />

(1) Relationship<br />

Management<br />

(2) Trust<br />

[relation-specific]<br />

Types <strong>of</strong> trust:<br />

- goodwill trust (integrity,<br />

consistency, loyalty, openness)<br />

- competency trust<br />

Cooperation on the basis <strong>of</strong> reciprocation<br />

(2) Reputation<br />

[perception-based]<br />

Desirable reputational traits:<br />

- reliable<br />

-trustworthy<br />

- transparent<br />

- honest<br />

Value Creation<br />

Figure 4-14: Links between relational embedding capabilities <strong>and</strong> value creation<br />

Rents through:<br />

- supportive stakeholders<br />

- lower transaction / governance cost<br />

- real options<br />

- access to capital market<br />

(3) Cultural & institutional adaptation: By means <strong>of</strong> cultural <strong>and</strong> institutional<br />

adaptation to match the implicit <strong>and</strong> explicit expectations <strong>of</strong> local<br />

stakeholders the firm may better reduce its liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness, thus<br />

overcoming related competitive disadvantage compared to firms <strong>of</strong> local<br />

origin. Adaptation <strong>of</strong> the firm's organisation, structures, <strong>and</strong> activities to the<br />

local environment positively affects its organisational legitimacy <strong>and</strong> the<br />

possibility to influence its environment in turn.<br />

Building local stakeholder relations. As postulated by stakeholder theory (see also<br />

section 4.6.1), effective stakeholder management is a critical requirement for corporate<br />

149


150<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

success. It includes the firm's processes <strong>of</strong> consultation, communication, dialogue <strong>and</strong><br />

exchange “to involve stakeholders in a positive manner in organisational activities”<br />

(Greenwood, 2007: 318). Different from the unidirectional stakeholder information,<br />

the building <strong>of</strong> stakeholder relations involves interaction <strong>and</strong> dialogue <strong>and</strong> sincere<br />

efforts to involve stakeholders in the firm's decision making (Röglin, 1994).<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> People Engaged<br />

Communication<br />

Strategies<br />

Information<br />

Disclosure<br />

Figure 4-15: Spectrum <strong>of</strong> stakeholder engagement 63<br />

Intensity <strong>of</strong> Engagement<br />

Consultation Participation<br />

Negotiation &<br />

Partnerships<br />

Whereas voluntary stakeholder information, discussed in the section on structural<br />

embedding capabilities, locates left in Figure 4-15, building relational ties involves<br />

more intensive stakeholder engagement. <strong>The</strong>reby firms are able to build social capital,<br />

i.e. the set <strong>of</strong> resources inherent in an actor's relationships (Coleman, 1988). Such relational<br />

resources develop through changes in the relations among persons that facilitate<br />

action. Consequently, these intangible, socially complex resources “may enhance<br />

firms' ability to outperform competitors in terms <strong>of</strong> long-term value creation” (Hillman<br />

& Keim, 2001:127; see also D. Davis & Mentzer, 2008; Hunt & Morgan, 1995).<br />

Example: Stakeholder relationship management at Holcim<br />

Holcim's engagement with stakeholders forms an integral part <strong>of</strong> its commitment to sustainable<br />

development (SD), which is embedded in its corporate strategy. Having recognised the relevance <strong>of</strong><br />

lasting stakeholder ties for its immediate <strong>and</strong> long-term performance, Holcim states in its 2007 SD<br />

report (2008: 23):<br />

At Holcim, developing <strong>and</strong> maintaining strong relationships with our stakeholders is vital to the<br />

success <strong>of</strong> our business. We are committed to a continuous process <strong>of</strong> listening to, <strong>and</strong> learning<br />

from, people <strong>and</strong> organisations engaged with our operations around the world. … Working in<br />

cooperation with organisations at global <strong>and</strong> local level is integral to maintaining our license to<br />

operate <strong>and</strong> helping to achieve a more sustainable future.<br />

Through these carefully built <strong>and</strong> maintained relations Holcim is able to increase the credibility <strong>of</strong> its<br />

social <strong>and</strong> environmental engagement, reinforced by cooperations <strong>and</strong> strategic corporate<br />

partnerships with organisations such as the German Agency for Technical Cooperation (GTZ) <strong>and</strong> the<br />

International Union for Conservation <strong>of</strong> Nature (IUCN). Both strengthen the firm's legitimacy by<br />

supporting it to find pragmatic solutions to Holcim's externalities <strong>and</strong> the thereto related challenges.<br />

63 International Finance Corporation, 2007.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Means <strong>of</strong> relationship-building. To establish relational ties with their stakeholders,<br />

firms' engagement practices pertain to many areas <strong>of</strong> organisational activity including<br />

public affairs, regulatory affairs, customer service, supplier relations, etc. <strong>The</strong>y may<br />

include activities such as community involvement through stakeholder panels,<br />

strategic partnerships with non-governmental organisations (NGO), <strong>and</strong> dialogues with<br />

authorities <strong>and</strong> related bodies. Most <strong>of</strong> these engagements involve a kind <strong>of</strong> dialogue,<br />

which Niedergesäß <strong>and</strong> Rettberg (1998) categorise in three principal types based on<br />

distinct motives: (1) sensitisation dialogues for early identification <strong>and</strong> reflection <strong>of</strong><br />

developments <strong>and</strong> issues in the firm's environment; (2) risk dialogues, which focus on<br />

firm-related social <strong>and</strong> ecological risks <strong>and</strong> aim at increasing stakeholder acceptance<br />

<strong>of</strong> these risks <strong>and</strong> the firm's measures to contain them; <strong>and</strong> (3) regulation dialogues,<br />

initiated upon a prevailing issue in order to exchange with affected stakeholders <strong>and</strong> to<br />

resolve related conflicts (see also Zöller, 2004). By carefully fostering such<br />

stakeholder engagement, firms are able to receive information, which enables them to<br />

sense emerging stakeholder issues in time, to take early actions, <strong>and</strong> thus to continue to<br />

satisfy stakeholder expectations. <strong>The</strong> ensuing example on Holcim provides an<br />

overview on their means to engage with stakeholders.<br />

Example: Types <strong>of</strong> stakeholder engagement at Holcim<br />

Holcim is committed to sustained engagement with a broad range <strong>of</strong> stakeholders. In 2009, 38% <strong>of</strong> its<br />

group companies had an established community advisory panel (CAP) <strong>and</strong> 83% conducted a<br />

stakeholder dialogue (Holcim, 2008) to give its stakeholders a platform. <strong>The</strong>se activities are<br />

complemented by a rich network <strong>of</strong> external partners, spanning the fields <strong>of</strong> community development,<br />

economic development, education, environment, health, <strong>and</strong> affordable housing <strong>and</strong> construction.<br />

Most noteworthy among those cooperations are Holcim's strategic corporate partnerships with GTZ<br />

<strong>and</strong> the International Union for Conservation <strong>of</strong> Nature IUCN. Table 4-7 illustrates how Holcim is<br />

committed to continuously improving its stakeholder dialogue <strong>and</strong> to increasing the use <strong>of</strong> CAP's.<br />

Type <strong>of</strong> engagement ▼ / % <strong>of</strong> group companies ► 2006 * 2007 * 2008 * 2009*<br />

Needs assessment 61% 65% 65% 46%<br />

Stakeholder involvement in CSR planning 80% 85% 83% 83%<br />

CSR/SD memberships 49% 70% 77% 79%<br />

Stakeholder dialogues 90% 89% 88% 83%<br />

Community advisory panels 39% 50% 54% 38%<br />

Cooperations 73% 76% 65% 67%<br />

* group companies covered in the years 2006: 49, 2007: 46, 2008: 48, <strong>and</strong> 2009: 48<br />

Table 4-7 Holcim's types <strong>of</strong> stakeholder engagement at the local level 64<br />

64<br />

Stakeholder engagement on a local level. Retrieved November 03, 2010, from Holcim corporate<br />

website: www.holcim.com/index.php?id=4356&L=1.<br />

151


152<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

In its 2009 SD Report (2010: 25), Holcim states: “Community engagement that results in mutual trust<br />

<strong>and</strong> social acceptance remains a priority for Holcim in all countries <strong>of</strong> operation. … Community<br />

advisory panels <strong>and</strong> other community engagement activities have proven to be an excellent way to<br />

collaborate with community stakeholders, share responsibilities <strong>and</strong> ensure project ownership”.<br />

Holcim aims at ultimately having a community engagement plan in place at all operational sites, an<br />

objective which it approaches stepwise through bi-annually increased targets.<br />

Effect on value creation. Within the scope <strong>of</strong> our research, we particularly focus on the<br />

moderating effects <strong>of</strong> such relationship management regarding the firm's institutional<br />

exposure <strong>and</strong> the impact on the latter's value creation. Being idiosyncratic to the firm,<br />

the value <strong>of</strong> relational resources lies in their use, brought to fruition when they are<br />

leveraged towards increasing the productiveness <strong>of</strong> other resources. Thus, they create<br />

value for the firm in two ways: on one h<strong>and</strong>, they have an enabling impact by opening<br />

up options for the firm in the future, which would not be in reach without its relational<br />

ties. On the other h<strong>and</strong> they have a risk-decreasing effect which lowers the firm's<br />

institutional exposure towards its stakeholders (Fombrun et al., 2000) <strong>and</strong> thus lowers<br />

overall transaction costs <strong>and</strong> the likelihood <strong>of</strong> opportunistic behaviour. Both effects<br />

will be described in more detail in our later discussion on value creation (cf. subchapters<br />

4.9.2 <strong>and</strong> 4.9.3).<br />

Summary. Firm's structured efforts to build <strong>and</strong> up-keep a dialogue with its relevant<br />

stakeholders lowers its institutional exposure, builds social capital <strong>and</strong> increases its<br />

overall legitimacy. Its resulting relational ties thereby are not only risk-decreasing, but<br />

also open up options for its future development.<br />

Reputation- <strong>and</strong> trust-building. Reputation <strong>and</strong> trust are idiosyncratic resources to<br />

the firm. <strong>The</strong>y both take time to be established, cannot be purchased <strong>and</strong> are easily<br />

damaged. Equally, both have multi-faceted characteristics <strong>and</strong> effects that made them<br />

objects <strong>of</strong> study in a number <strong>of</strong> disciplines, including economic sociology,<br />

organisation theory, strategic management, <strong>and</strong> economics. Within our research<br />

framework, we look at both constructs mainly through the lenses <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

sociology <strong>and</strong> strategic management.<br />

Reputation. Within economic sociology, reputation is considered as socially<br />

constructed <strong>and</strong> defined as “a global perception <strong>of</strong> the extent to which an organisation<br />

is held in high esteem or regard by the organisation's multiple stakeholders” (A. Weiss,<br />

Anderson, & MacInnis, 1999). Reputation therefore is subject to causal ambiguity <strong>and</strong><br />

social complexity, constituting “subjective collective assessments <strong>of</strong> the<br />

trustworthiness <strong>and</strong> reliability <strong>of</strong> firms” (Fombrun & Van Riel, 1997: 10). It represents<br />

an external reflection <strong>of</strong> internal sense making activities within the firm.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Complementarily, from a strategic management perspective reputation is viewed as a<br />

strategic resource <strong>and</strong> a mobility barrier which “produce[s] tangible benefits: premium<br />

prices for products, lower costs for capital <strong>and</strong> labour, improved loyalty from<br />

employees, greater latitude in decision making, <strong>and</strong> a cushion <strong>of</strong> goodwill when crises<br />

hit” (Fombrun, 1996: 57). Under this view the firm's main motivation for activities<br />

towards building a reputation pertains to the strengthening <strong>of</strong> its competitive<br />

advantage. <strong>The</strong> subsequent two examples illustrate a highly effective approach to<br />

reputation-management: Holcim combines conscious internal sense-making with an<br />

active communication strategy <strong>and</strong> thus successfully builds its reputation as a good<br />

corporate citizen.<br />

Example: Holcim's conscious reputation-building<br />

Under the credo 'we want to be the world's most respected company in our industry' Holcim<br />

consciously builds its reputation as a global socially responsible industry leader. In a presentation on<br />

the management <strong>of</strong> reputation 65 , it identifies the following preconditions towards achieving this goal:<br />

- reliability <strong>of</strong> its management<br />

- adherence to Holcim's own code <strong>of</strong> conduct <strong>and</strong> the reliance on its own integrity<br />

- being a fair competitor (see also Holcim’s Corporate Code <strong>of</strong> Conduct)<br />

- focus on operational safety <strong>and</strong> health by means <strong>of</strong> Holcim's 'passion for safety' initiative <strong>and</strong><br />

maintaining <strong>of</strong> a record <strong>of</strong> excellence<br />

- true commitment to sustainable development <strong>and</strong> external recognition for its efforts<br />

Holcim passed a number <strong>of</strong> milestones to build the reputation it aims for:<br />

1999 creation <strong>of</strong> an environmental management committee<br />

1999 start <strong>of</strong> the WBCSD cement sustainability initiative, <strong>of</strong> with Holcim is one <strong>of</strong> the initiators<br />

2001 introduction <strong>of</strong> a corporate environmental policy<br />

2002 publication <strong>of</strong> the first corporate sustainability report<br />

2002 introduction <strong>of</strong> the corporate policy on the use <strong>of</strong> alternative fuel <strong>and</strong> raw materials<br />

2003 strategic partnership with GTZ<br />

2003 signing <strong>of</strong> the UN Global Compact<br />

2003 policy on corporate social responsibility<br />

2003 introduction <strong>of</strong> the corporate policy on fair competition<br />

2003 creation <strong>of</strong> a Sustainable Development steering committee<br />

2004 introduction <strong>of</strong> a corporate code <strong>of</strong> conduct<br />

2004 second corporate sustainable development (CSD) report<br />

Holcim continuously reinforces the direction <strong>of</strong> impact these milestones had on the company <strong>and</strong> the<br />

industry, e.g. by committing itself to stepwise CO2 reduction targets.<br />

65 Dubach, B. (Holcim Ltd) (2005). Is reputation manageable - a benchmarking exercise. Workshop at<br />

the Sustainability Forum, held in Zurich, September 13, 2005. Retrieved August 11, 2010, from:<br />

www.sustainability-zurich.org/cm_data/TSF_2005_32_Dubach_Workshop2.pdf.<br />

153


154<br />

Example: Transparency <strong>and</strong> good governance - Holcim <strong>and</strong> the media<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Holcim imparts the media an important role in strengthening its reputation <strong>and</strong> in informing the<br />

public on its qualities as a good corporate citizen. Careful to invigorate its “license to operate”,<br />

Holcim's information policy is governed by the principles <strong>of</strong> openness <strong>and</strong> transparency, impartiality<br />

<strong>and</strong> promptness, as well as accessibility <strong>and</strong> regional policy. On its homepage, the firm states “we are<br />

committed to creating effective communications that enable our stakeholders to make informed<br />

decisions about our goals <strong>and</strong> performance” 66 . In an effort to intensify its relationships with<br />

journalists, Holcim's country organisations regularly invite media representatives to its production<br />

units <strong>and</strong> its social <strong>and</strong> environmental projects 67 . Holcim has chosen a pro-active approach in<br />

involving <strong>and</strong> using the media for legitimacy-reinforcing reputation-building.<br />

<strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> reputation loss. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, relative to the firm's institutional<br />

exposure to its environment, damage to reputation may become an issue to corporate<br />

survival. Often cited for such major loss <strong>of</strong> reputation are two cases involving Shell,<br />

see next example.<br />

Example: Shell's 1996 loss <strong>of</strong> reputation <strong>and</strong> ensuing crisis<br />

In 1996 Shell went through a major crisis, caused by public outrage concerning its planned<br />

dismantling <strong>of</strong> the Brent-Spar oil platform <strong>and</strong> its social <strong>and</strong> environmental practices in Nigeria <strong>and</strong><br />

an ensuing consumer boycott. After this loss <strong>of</strong> legitimacy it took the company years to change its<br />

culture <strong>and</strong> to rebuild its reputation, before emerging as a pioneer in CSR <strong>and</strong> triple bottom line<br />

reporting. Shell learnt that short-term oriented opportunistic (<strong>and</strong> non-ethical) behaviour involves<br />

major reputational risks which might cause costs <strong>and</strong> inhibit future contracting opportunities (cf. B.<br />

Taylor, 2006).<br />

Evidenly, Shell's crisis was on a global scale, beyond the scope <strong>of</strong> our dissertation.<br />

Nevertheless, the example illustrates impressively, how the loss <strong>of</strong> legitimacy on a<br />

local level may become an issue <strong>of</strong> a much wider dimension. If the firm lacks - local<br />

<strong>and</strong> overall - goodwill stocks, that need to be built over longer time through reputation<br />

<strong>and</strong> stakeholder trust, it is not able to draw on them in case <strong>of</strong> unexpected events. As<br />

the more recent example <strong>of</strong> BP's oil catastrophe in the Gulf <strong>of</strong> Mexico in 2010 shows,<br />

such reputational goodwill stocks can be destroyed within a short time, if the firm does<br />

not adequately respond through transparent information, responsible actions, <strong>and</strong><br />

sufficient commitment to rectify its failings.<br />

66<br />

Press <strong>and</strong> Media. Retrieved June 12,2010 from Holcim corporate website:<br />

www.holcim.com/CORP/EN/id/1610644015/mod/6/page/channel.html.<br />

67<br />

Cf. Holcim Brazil (2008), Corporate Sustainable Development 2007;<br />

www.holdercim.com/gc/BR/uploads/TEXTOS_FINAL_ENGLISH.pdf.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Value creation effects <strong>of</strong> good reputation. Reputation is built through investments in<br />

the fulfilment <strong>of</strong> promises with regard to implicit stakeholder claims <strong>and</strong> signals that<br />

such claims will be honoured also in future. Its capacity to impact the firm through the<br />

system <strong>of</strong> markets, including capital markets, input-, <strong>and</strong> output markets consequently<br />

give it an economic value (Hill, 1990) which increases with the firm's vulnerability<br />

<strong>and</strong> institutional exposure. <strong>The</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> a positive corporate reputation as an<br />

indicator for being a good corporate citizen <strong>and</strong> high organisational legitimacy are<br />

summarised in Table 4-8.<br />

Efficiency, cost<br />

Crisis management reputation as a good corporate citizen lower follow-up cost through<br />

“cushion <strong>of</strong> goodwill when crises hit” (Fombrun, 1996: 57)<br />

Transaction & selection<br />

cost<br />

reputation for non-opportunistic behaviour reduces cost <strong>of</strong> contracting &<br />

monitoring <strong>and</strong> facilitates the establishment <strong>of</strong> stable relationships <strong>and</strong><br />

lower cost <strong>of</strong> partner selection<br />

Financing cost reputation as an indicator <strong>of</strong> high legitimacy lowers cost <strong>of</strong> capital<br />

Quality & Productivity reputation as a good corporate citizen leads to higher morale <strong>and</strong><br />

motivation <strong>of</strong> actors involved in the firm's production processes, e.g.<br />

suppliers <strong>and</strong> employees working for the firm<br />

Strategy, competitive advantage<br />

Mobility barrier rent-creation due to difficult to imitate <strong>and</strong> unique positioning with<br />

stakeholders<br />

Goodwill stock <strong>of</strong> goodwill in case <strong>of</strong> reputation shock, contributing to<br />

stakeholder's cooperative attitude, helping to master crisis more quickly<br />

<strong>and</strong> with less (reputational) damage<br />

Opportunities additional contracting opportunities <strong>and</strong> attraction <strong>of</strong> desirable firm<br />

partners <strong>and</strong> talents (employee recruitment) due to reputation-based firm<br />

attractiveness<br />

Signalling rent-creation through signalling <strong>of</strong> superiority <strong>of</strong> firm, regarding product<br />

quality, corporate citizenship, competitors, etc.<br />

Table 4-8: Efficiency <strong>and</strong> strategy-based advantages <strong>of</strong> corporate reputation<br />

Importance <strong>of</strong> UCF for reputation. In the relations with its local environment,<br />

corporate reputation is a major factor for our research object. As a result <strong>of</strong> the high<br />

visibility, spatial inflexibility, <strong>and</strong> the related institutional exposure, reputational<br />

effects may be stronger for the UCF than for a footloose firm. Consequently,<br />

reputation may be regarded as a strategic asset for the location-fix firm, crucial to<br />

155


156<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

attaining competitive advantage. <strong>The</strong> UCF's reputation-building activities therefore<br />

represent an essential element in the efforts to limit institutional exposure <strong>and</strong> to create<br />

value.<br />

Trust. Trust entails “the expectation that an actor (1) can be relied on to fulfil<br />

obligations, (2) will behave in a predictable manner, <strong>and</strong> (3) will act <strong>and</strong> negotiate<br />

fairly when the possibility for opportunism is present” (A. Zaheer et al., 1998: 143). It<br />

is characterised by the absence <strong>of</strong> formal safeguards in interactions, such as<br />

guarantees, complete contracts, <strong>and</strong> juridical enforcement (Gössling, 2004) <strong>and</strong><br />

develops only in repeated interactions <strong>and</strong> long-lasting relationships with identifiable<br />

interaction partners. Generally, the trustworthiness <strong>of</strong> a firm is associated with<br />

behavioural routines, but also with its ethics <strong>and</strong> values, all <strong>of</strong> which are part <strong>of</strong> an<br />

organisation's culture (Nooteboom, 1996).<br />

Challenges <strong>of</strong> conceptualisation. While there is general consensus on the importance<br />

<strong>of</strong> trust in human conduct, research ostensibly lacks agreement on how to<br />

conceptualise trust suitably, discussing it on the basis <strong>of</strong> numerous levels <strong>and</strong> units <strong>of</strong><br />

analysis (Shapiro, 1987). One <strong>of</strong> the difficulties <strong>of</strong> conceptualisation pertains to the<br />

context, within which trust is discussed, which may relate to individual expectations,<br />

interpersonal relationships, social structures, ethical principles, or economic<br />

exchanges. With reference to economic or inter-organisational exchange, trust can be<br />

seen as a specialised form <strong>of</strong> interpersonal trust (Hosmer, 1995) - a simplification<br />

which creates its own set <strong>of</strong> challenges: Zaheer & al. (1998) contend that, although<br />

inter-personal <strong>and</strong> inter-organisational trust are related, they are distinct constructs.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se differences need to be considered appropriately in the conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

role <strong>of</strong> trust in economic exchange. More specifically, organisations are not able to<br />

build trust as an entity; it is the individuals representing the organisation who establish<br />

trust. Trust therefore, as an aspect <strong>of</strong> relationships, varies within persons <strong>and</strong> across<br />

relationships. As a consequence, Zaheer et al. (ibid.) suggest two distinct definitions to<br />

resolve this ambiguity: they define interpersonal trust as the extent <strong>of</strong> a boundaryspanning<br />

agent's trust in his counterpart in the partner organisation. On the other h<strong>and</strong><br />

inter-organisational trust is the extent <strong>of</strong> trust placed in the partner organisation by the<br />

members <strong>of</strong> a focal organisation. Boundary spanners thereby are members <strong>of</strong> the<br />

organisation, who are more closely involved in the inter-organisational relationship<br />

<strong>and</strong> interaction with their counterparts than other members.<br />

Thus, in order to underst<strong>and</strong> the multilevel phenomena <strong>of</strong> trust, inter-organisational<br />

relationships have to be analysed on the individual <strong>and</strong> organisational level


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

simultaneously. By institutionalising processes, the individual <strong>and</strong> organisational trustbuilding<br />

are linked, stabilising role definitions, even though individual boundary<br />

spanners might change.<br />

In the context <strong>of</strong> inter-organisational exchange <strong>and</strong> governance structures, a further<br />

conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> trust seems noteworthy, distinguishing between a partner's ability<br />

to perform according to agreements - termed competence trust - <strong>and</strong> his intentions to<br />

do so - referred to as goodwill trust (Nooteboom, 1996). Both types <strong>of</strong> trust are<br />

relevant to our research framework, which is concerned with inter-organisational trust<br />

between the firm <strong>and</strong> its institutional stakeholders, i.e. inter-firm relationships <strong>and</strong><br />

firm-'public stakeholder' relationships, but also with firm relations to stakeholders as<br />

individuals.<br />

Value creation effects <strong>of</strong> trust. An early suggestion <strong>of</strong> a link between trust <strong>and</strong> value<br />

creation interestingly stems from Kenneth Arrow (1972: 357), one <strong>of</strong> the most<br />

influential neoclassical economists <strong>of</strong> the 21 st century, who claims that<br />

virtually every commercial transaction has within itself an element <strong>of</strong> trust,<br />

certainly any transaction conducted over a period <strong>of</strong> time. It can be plausibly<br />

argued that much <strong>of</strong> the economic backwardness in the world can be explained by<br />

the lack <strong>of</strong> mutual confidence.<br />

Attributing equal importance to trust, Allan Greenspan defines it as a form <strong>of</strong> social<br />

organisation, putting it at the root <strong>of</strong> any economic system based on mutually<br />

beneficial exchange: “in virtually all transactions, we rely on the word <strong>of</strong> those with<br />

whom we do business. Were this not the case, exchange <strong>of</strong> goods <strong>and</strong> services could<br />

not take place on any reasonable scale” (Greenspan, 1999). <strong>The</strong> role <strong>of</strong> trust in<br />

enabling transactions in a world <strong>of</strong> incomplete contracts therefore may be rated as<br />

invaluable. How then can firms, <strong>and</strong> in particular our research object, use trust to<br />

create competitive advantage <strong>and</strong> sustainable rents? On the basis <strong>of</strong> their long-term<br />

orientation UCFs have an interest to establish enduring working relationships with<br />

their key stakeholders. In addition, their dependence on the location makes them<br />

highly committed towards their selected partners. As a consequence, their repeated<br />

interactions over time allow for the development <strong>of</strong> mutually trust-based relationships.<br />

Trust thereby acts as governance mechanism <strong>of</strong> such embedded relationships,<br />

facilitating “the exchange <strong>of</strong> resources <strong>and</strong> information that are crucial for high<br />

performance but are difficult to value <strong>and</strong> transfer via market ties” (Uzzi, 1996: 678).<br />

Furthermore, the associated access to tacit <strong>and</strong> strategic know-how increases the firm's<br />

transactional efficacy <strong>and</strong> renders it more responsive to external developments. As a<br />

157


158<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

result,the firm benefits from efficiency gains in governance, eased negotiations <strong>and</strong><br />

consequently lower costs <strong>of</strong> reaching mutually acceptable agreements (A. Zaheer et<br />

al., 1998). With the prospect <strong>of</strong> these advantages, the partners in trust-based<br />

relationships have material incentives for cooperation <strong>and</strong> reduce their relationshipspecific<br />

uncertainty. <strong>The</strong> longer such relationships hold, with a sound prospect <strong>of</strong><br />

future relational benefits, the higher the impact on mutual trust <strong>and</strong> trustworthiness.<br />

<strong>The</strong> efficiency-related <strong>and</strong> strategic advantages <strong>of</strong> trust in business relationships are<br />

summarised in Table 4-9.<br />

Efficiency, cost<br />

Uncertainty decrease in governance costs <strong>and</strong> cooperation under reduced uncertainty<br />

Negotiation cost faster agreements with lesser safeguards <strong>and</strong> contracting costs<br />

Selection cost establishment <strong>of</strong> stable relationship <strong>and</strong> lower cost <strong>of</strong> partner selection<br />

Strategy, competitive advantage<br />

Reaction time faster reaction to unforeseen events<br />

Conflict resolution constructive settling <strong>of</strong> conflict <strong>and</strong> lower risk <strong>of</strong> ex-post opportunism<br />

Information exchange timely exchange <strong>of</strong> fine-grained information<br />

Innovativeness higher innovativeness <strong>of</strong> mutually trusting parties<br />

Cooperation increased willingness for cooperation between partners<br />

Relationship-specific<br />

investments<br />

higher willingness to incur relationship-specific cost <strong>and</strong> to take risks<br />

Table 4-9: Efficiency <strong>and</strong> strategy-based advantages <strong>of</strong> trusting relationships<br />

Summary. Thus, if the local management <strong>of</strong> a UCF succeeds to build a credible<br />

reputation as a good corporate citizen <strong>and</strong> to make trust a crucial element <strong>of</strong> their<br />

stakeholder relations, it contributes to sustainable value creation for the firm. Such<br />

added value goes beyond the short term <strong>and</strong> may not always be quantifiable. Rather, it<br />

may manifest itself in the creation <strong>of</strong> real options for future business development by<br />

activating stakeholders' cooperation potential, or by freeing management attention<br />

from controlling <strong>and</strong> conflict resolution to more strategic tasks, since reduced<br />

uncertainty allows firms to adopt a longer-term orientation (Knack & Keefer, 1997).<br />

Firm adaptation to local context. This element <strong>of</strong> the UCF's relational (social)<br />

embedding capabilities provides a bridge to the second part <strong>of</strong> the research framework,


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

the multi-site perspective. <strong>The</strong> adaptation to the local context, as a moderating factor<br />

to the firm's institutional exposure involves more challenging obstacles for non-local<br />

firms, compared to firms which are familiar with their institutional context. <strong>The</strong>refore,<br />

the following passages concentrate on local branches <strong>of</strong> multi-site firms, <strong>and</strong> their<br />

endeavours <strong>and</strong> challenges to embed themselves in their new institutional<br />

environment.<br />

<strong>The</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> the firm's alignment with its institutional environment for its longterm<br />

survival is a central notion <strong>of</strong> institutionalism. <strong>The</strong>reby, the “conformity <strong>of</strong><br />

organizations to the collective normative order increases the flow <strong>of</strong> societal<br />

resources” (Zucker, 1987: 445), thus strengthening the firm's organisational<br />

legitimacy. As a consequence, the firm is induced to adopt structures or processes<br />

reflecting its institutional environment, defined as a “set <strong>of</strong> highly established <strong>and</strong><br />

culturally sanctioned action patterns <strong>and</strong> expectations” (Lincoln, Hanada, & McBride,<br />

1986: 340). <strong>The</strong>se incentives for adaptation are referred to as coercive isomorphism<br />

(DiMaggio & Powell, 1983), which is based on formal <strong>and</strong> informal pressures by other<br />

entities upon which the firm is dependent <strong>and</strong> on the cultural expectations in the<br />

society within which the firm functions. As a response to these external pressures, the<br />

firm's capacity to align itself with the institutional environment's expectations<br />

decisively depends on its local management's ability to sense these expectations, <strong>and</strong><br />

its collaborative capabilities.<br />

Liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness. For firms which are active in cultural <strong>and</strong> institutional<br />

environments outside their home territory, such adaptation to the local environment<br />

may involve additional challenges: they may experience disadvantages referred to as<br />

liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness (see also section 4.2.4). <strong>The</strong> latter refer to costs that a firm <strong>of</strong><br />

local origin would not incur <strong>and</strong> which put the focal firm's branch at a competitive<br />

disadvantage. Liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness arise from four interdependent sources (S.<br />

Zaheer, 1995), namely (1) spatial distance, involving liabilities such as travel,<br />

transportation, <strong>and</strong> coordination over distance; (2) unfamiliarity with <strong>and</strong> lack <strong>of</strong> roots<br />

in a local environment; (3) lack <strong>of</strong> legitimacy in the host-environment <strong>and</strong> economic<br />

chauvinism; <strong>and</strong> (4) home-country-environment-induced costs. <strong>The</strong> firm's ability to<br />

adapt to the local environment is particularly relevant to overcome the second <strong>and</strong><br />

third source, i.e. the unfamiliarity to the local environment <strong>and</strong> the lack <strong>of</strong> legitimacy<br />

in this environment. Within the scope <strong>of</strong> our research framework, these two liabilityinducing<br />

factors do not only affect multi-national firms operating across nation states.<br />

Much rather, we relate foreignness generally to unfamiliarity <strong>and</strong> legitimacy-issues <strong>of</strong><br />

a firm in a new territory, independent <strong>of</strong> national borders. As will be illustrated in the<br />

159


160<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

subsequent example, as well as the later case description <strong>of</strong> Axpo (see chapter 5.1.3),<br />

the institutional structures <strong>of</strong> a country, its size, <strong>and</strong> its ethnical composition may lead<br />

to the formation <strong>of</strong> very different institutional environments, to which even a firm<br />

from the same national background may be foreign, if it originates from a different<br />

region.<br />

Example: Home territories <strong>of</strong> Swiss Electricity Utilities, Axpo's expansion efforts<br />

Despite the compactness <strong>of</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong> as a country, its 41'000km2 entail an impressive variety in<br />

cultural identities <strong>and</strong> local populations - many <strong>of</strong> them with a distinct sense <strong>of</strong> belonging. Related to<br />

these regional identities some areas are characterised by economic chauvinism, erecting mobility<br />

barriers for outsiders including firms from other parts <strong>of</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong>. Such barriers are noticeable to<br />

power utilities, since most <strong>of</strong> the incumbent firms are embedded <strong>and</strong> protected in their territory <strong>of</strong><br />

origin, but are hardly able to move beyond into other incumbents' territories. Axpo, for instance,<br />

repeatedly tried to get a foothold in other water-rich areas. <strong>The</strong>reby, it faced obstacles such as the<br />

delay <strong>of</strong> approval processes, due to the authorities' request for additional investigations which usually<br />

are undertaken at a later stage. Other obstacles emerged in the form <strong>of</strong> imposed conditions which<br />

render the project economically or politically unattractive, <strong>and</strong> which would result in political issues<br />

which the firm wants to avoid. This way, the procedural slow-down allows the local incumbent to<br />

regain lost time in order to ultimately come up with a request for approval <strong>of</strong> its own (cf. interviews<br />

N°1: 15; N°3: 18).<br />

Among the strategies to overcome any liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness, local firms may<br />

choose a compensatory approach by deploying additional skills <strong>and</strong> capabilities in the<br />

local context, transferred from outside-in. As a result, the firm might be able to derive<br />

competitive advantage from its superior organisational capabilities <strong>and</strong> its abilities to<br />

learn, respectively transfer organisational practices <strong>and</strong> managerial skills across its<br />

portfolio <strong>of</strong> sites (see also discussion <strong>of</strong> the multi-site perspective in sub-chapter 4.10).<br />

Alternatively, firms may opt for an adaptive strategy, reducing the liabilities <strong>of</strong><br />

foreignness by being locally responsive <strong>and</strong> by conforming to the expectations <strong>of</strong> their<br />

local stakeholders. In most cases non-local multi-site firms employ a combination <strong>of</strong><br />

both strategies for their local subunits, trying to find a balance between the<br />

headquarters' pressures for internal consistency <strong>and</strong> the local coercive isomorphism<br />

(Rosenzweig & Singh, 1991).<br />

Example: Holcim's Garadagh operation in Azerbaijan<br />

In 1999, Holcim acquired Garadagh Cement, Azerbaijan's market leader in the cement industry. Soon<br />

Holcim's local management became aware <strong>of</strong> the high relationship-orientation <strong>of</strong> the Azeri culture<br />

<strong>and</strong> the related importance <strong>of</strong> intense relationship-management with the firm's stakeholders.<br />

Particularly to be on good terms with local authorities proved to be decisive for business<br />

performance. Holcim's country manager summarises this cultural property: “It is important to be in


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

continuous communication with the relevant people. No communication might be perceived as<br />

arrogant. … It took me three years to find out how this works in Azerbaijan. I had to learn everything<br />

from zero, all the relationships inside the government, between the political <strong>and</strong> regional players, etc.<br />

… If you learn the local language, know the local culture, <strong>and</strong> respect the local traditions … people<br />

will respect you much easier” (interview N°7: 9). According to him, Holcim successfully embedded<br />

itself in Azerbaijan partly because it “does not want to change the culture <strong>of</strong> the country company,<br />

where it is present. … <strong>The</strong>re are only few people delegated from the headquarters, <strong>and</strong> they try to<br />

adapt the Holcim culture to the local culture, not the other way round” (ibid.: 2). By successfully<br />

blending the strengths <strong>of</strong> the local culture with the know-how, best practices <strong>and</strong> corporate<br />

governance st<strong>and</strong>ards from the corporate centre, Holcim managed to continuously increase the local<br />

cement output <strong>and</strong> plant efficiency. In addition, its relationship-building with the local authorities<br />

created value, for example, through an alignment <strong>of</strong> Azeri cement st<strong>and</strong>ards with European st<strong>and</strong>ards,<br />

thus increasing its range <strong>of</strong> products from initially two to six differing cement types.<br />

Adapting along the institutional pillars. To successfully blend into the local<br />

environment, the firm's local branch needs to adapt on all previously mentioned<br />

institutional dimensions, i.e. the (1) regulative (what the firm may or must not do); the<br />

(2) normative (what the firm should <strong>and</strong> should not do); <strong>and</strong> the (3) cognitive<br />

dimension (what is or is not true, respectively what the firm can or cannot do) (see also<br />

Scott, 2001). On the regulative dimension, the firm is exposed to coercive pressures<br />

for isomorphism (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983), which almost leave it no choice than to<br />

adapt, such as to safeguard its organisational legitimacy. This adaptation is fairly<br />

straightforward, since the legal <strong>and</strong> regulatory expectations are explicit <strong>and</strong> seizable.<br />

More challenging, the normative dimension depends on the ability <strong>of</strong> the local<br />

management to sense less explicit local expectations, <strong>and</strong> to consequently derive the<br />

right embedding actions. Thus, managers may seek legitimacy in conforming <strong>and</strong><br />

signalling allegiance to the cultural order <strong>and</strong> to established institutional logics (Meyer<br />

& Rowan, 1991). Ultimately, the subliminal cultural-cognitive dimension presents the<br />

most dem<strong>and</strong>ing form <strong>of</strong> embeddedness, being reflected in the shared underst<strong>and</strong>ings<br />

<strong>and</strong> meanings that give form to the firm's activities, structures, <strong>and</strong> processes (Dacin et<br />

al., 1999). Inability to comply with expectations on this dimension may potentially<br />

damage the firm's legitimacy. To avoid such frictions, managers with a non-local<br />

background therefore may choose to bring in locally rooted actors for support.<br />

Effect on value creation. <strong>The</strong> influence between the firm <strong>and</strong> its embedded context is a<br />

bi-directional one. Firms do not only experience it as a constraint, but they perceive<br />

also distinct opportunity sets that embeddedness creates. Put differently, while firms<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten adapt to their institutional contexts, they are equally active in shaping those<br />

contexts, i.e. trying to incorporate their goals <strong>and</strong> structures into the rules <strong>of</strong><br />

161


162<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

institutions <strong>and</strong> authorities (Dowling & Pfeffer, 1975). This notion is supported by a<br />

statement <strong>of</strong> Holcim's country manager in Azerbaijan: “It is important that one does<br />

not appear too … rigid to the environment - one always needs to be adaptable.<br />

Adaptability is very important in terms <strong>of</strong> relationship with the local environment. If<br />

they see, that you are adaptable, they are also willing to be adaptable” (interview N°7:<br />

10f.).<br />

Summary. By prudently adapting the firm's structures to the local institutional context,<br />

the firm is able to overcome obstacles <strong>and</strong> to create options for its future development.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se options, on one h<strong>and</strong>, are created through the effects <strong>of</strong> a high organisational<br />

legitimacy, <strong>and</strong> on the other h<strong>and</strong>, through the reciprocal effect which the firm's<br />

willingness to adapt has on its stakeholders' response. Thus, the firm gains influence<br />

<strong>and</strong> possibilities to shape its local environment, thereby increasing its chances for<br />

survival <strong>and</strong> creating opportunities for competitive advantage.<br />

4.8.6 Summary <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities<br />

<strong>The</strong> firm's capabilities to embed itself in its local environment <strong>and</strong> to facilitate its<br />

organisational legitimisation process are summarised in Table 4-10. In this context it<br />

needs to be emphasised that the suggested operationalisation <strong>of</strong> some characteristics<br />

needs to remain vague, due to the latter's multi-dimensionality <strong>and</strong> conceptual overlap.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Embedding<br />

capabilities<br />

Description Operationalisation<br />

Structural (economic):<br />

Tangible activities which manifest the firm's commitment to its location beyond symbolic actions<br />

<strong>and</strong> which protect its interests against uncertainty <strong>and</strong> risks <strong>of</strong> opportunism<br />

Value share<br />

remaining<br />

in region<br />

Hostages<br />

<strong>and</strong> mutual<br />

lock-in<br />

Selfmonitoring<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

governance<br />

Deliberate redistribution by the<br />

firm <strong>of</strong> a part <strong>of</strong> its rents to<br />

local stakeholders, in order to<br />

create intangible assets that<br />

create value or prevent value<br />

destruction<br />

Protection <strong>of</strong> the firm's interests<br />

through creation <strong>of</strong> a balanced<br />

mutual dependence to<br />

compensate for the<br />

incompleteness <strong>of</strong> contracts <strong>and</strong><br />

the related uncertainty <strong>and</strong><br />

opportunistic risks<br />

Reinforcement <strong>of</strong> the firm's<br />

social contract through credible<br />

self-regulation beyond regulative<br />

institutional necessity<br />

Spending for firm policies, programmes, initiatives <strong>and</strong><br />

processes that are directed at compensating stakeholders<br />

for the firm's externalities.<br />

Examples: locally paid taxes, sustainable livelihood<br />

wages, CSR-related projects<br />

(1) Credible threat <strong>of</strong> third-party enforcement; (2) formal<br />

safeguards (self-enforcing incentive structure);<br />

(3) informal safeguards (trust based lock-in based on high<br />

mutual asset-specificity, reinforced by contractual<br />

disincentives for cheating)<br />

Examples pertaining to the public stakeholders:<br />

(1) foreign state, from which the firm originates or which<br />

has a vital interest in the firm's success; (2) ex-ante<br />

credible commitment through upfront financial support;<br />

(3) penalties<br />

Social <strong>and</strong> environmental accounting, voluntary<br />

monitoring activities, publication <strong>of</strong> data <strong>and</strong> corrective<br />

actions.<br />

Examples: tracking / publication <strong>of</strong> negative externalities<br />

Relational (social):<br />

Activities to build relational <strong>and</strong> reputational assets towards institutional isomorphism<br />

<strong>Local</strong><br />

stakeholder<br />

relations<br />

Reputation-<br />

<strong>and</strong> trustbuilding<br />

Adaptation<br />

to local<br />

context<br />

Establishment <strong>and</strong> cultivation<br />

<strong>of</strong> strong local stakeholder<br />

relations for mutual benefit,<br />

thus building relational capital<br />

to reduce risks <strong>and</strong> create value<br />

By means <strong>of</strong> the firm's past <strong>and</strong><br />

current behaviour it signals to<br />

stakeholders the future<br />

behaviour that they can expect:<br />

through these investments in<br />

promises the firm reduces<br />

uncertainty & transaction costs<br />

Conforming to local stakeholders'<br />

expectations strengthens<br />

the firm's local legitimacy <strong>and</strong><br />

increases its ability to influence<br />

its local environment<br />

Table 4-10: Summary <strong>and</strong> operationalisation <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities<br />

Structured <strong>and</strong> deliberate stakeholder engagement<br />

activities.<br />

Examples: stakeholder dialogue, CAPs, cooperations <strong>and</strong><br />

strategic partnerships with interest groups, engagement<br />

level in public affairs, regulatory affairs<br />

Defined through context-specific factors for the individual<br />

stakeholder groups.<br />

Examples: ranking <strong>of</strong> firm attractiveness as employer<br />

among university graduates, attributed firm creditworthiness<br />

from banks, delivery <strong>and</strong> payment terms from<br />

suppliers, quality <strong>of</strong> relationship with regulator<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> stakeholder conflicts compared to closest<br />

benchmark within same / similar institutional<br />

environment.<br />

Examples: labour conflicts, regulatory fines, number <strong>of</strong><br />

legal cases <strong>of</strong> local scope<br />

163


164<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

After this in-depth discussion <strong>of</strong> our framework’s moderator <strong>of</strong> the relationship<br />

between UCF's local exposure <strong>and</strong> its capacity for value creation, the next section will<br />

be concerned entirely with value creation.<br />

4.9 Value creation<br />

With the firm as our unit <strong>of</strong> analysis, we will begin by highlighting the conceptual<br />

issues regarding firm-level value creation. After an introduction to value creation in<br />

general, we will continue with a discussion <strong>of</strong> the dimensions <strong>of</strong> our output variable:<br />

the creation <strong>of</strong> strategic options; the reduction <strong>of</strong> business risks; <strong>and</strong> value-creating<br />

short-term effects to the firm, as illustrated in Figure 4-16.<br />

embedding<br />

capabilities (4.8)<br />

local exposure from<br />

moderate<br />

location fixity (4.5 - 4.7) value creation (4.9)<br />

influences<br />

strategic options (4.9.2)<br />

risk decrease (4.9.3)<br />

short-term effects (4.9.4)<br />

Figure 4-16: Value creation as the dependent (output) variable within the research framework<br />

Challenges in conceptualisation. <strong>The</strong> concept <strong>of</strong> value has been embraced by a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> research perspectives <strong>and</strong> represents an important notion in addressing<br />

questions such as why firms exist <strong>and</strong> why they perform differently. As Conner (1991)<br />

notes, the primary pursuit <strong>of</strong> business is creating <strong>and</strong> maintaining value. But despite<br />

the centrality <strong>of</strong> value creation, value itself remains an ambiguous notion with little<br />

agreement among researchers on what value means or how it is created 68 . <strong>The</strong><br />

difficulties in conceptualising resource value as well as value creation lie in their<br />

multiplexity (cf. Peteraf, 2005), which results in the following dilemmas:<br />

(1) System boundaries. Which is the unit <strong>of</strong> interest in value creation, the firm<br />

alone, as part <strong>of</strong> a network, as part <strong>of</strong> the local environment <strong>and</strong> society, or the<br />

economy as a whole?<br />

68 Within the discussion <strong>of</strong> strategic management research, Rumelt (2003) identifies four areas <strong>of</strong><br />

confusion with regard to value creation <strong>and</strong> competitive advantage: (1) disagreement about how value<br />

should be conceptualised or measured, (2) confusion about the meaning <strong>of</strong> rents, (3) disagreement<br />

over the appropriate use <strong>of</strong> the opportunity cost concept, <strong>and</strong> (4) disagreement on the meaning <strong>of</strong><br />

competitive advantage (winning the game versus maintaining a position in the game).


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

(2) Exchange versus use value. Is the value <strong>of</strong> a resource measured in terms <strong>of</strong> a<br />

transaction price (exchange value) or with regard to the use for the firm (value<br />

in use)? Is the resource value to be determined relative to the firm's competitors,<br />

the value created for customers, or in terms <strong>of</strong> the rent the resource generates<br />

internally?<br />

(3) <strong>The</strong> value <strong>of</strong> real options. Does value consider real assets only or does it include<br />

the value <strong>of</strong> strategic flexibility <strong>and</strong> future options <strong>of</strong> a firm?<br />

(4) Value creation versus value capture. Ultimately not the firm's value creation<br />

(increasing the size <strong>of</strong> the pie) is reflected in its bottom line, but which part <strong>of</strong><br />

the created value (share <strong>of</strong> the pie) it eventually captures <strong>and</strong> retains.<br />

(1) System boundaries. <strong>The</strong> value that a firm creates may be seen from different<br />

angles, resulting in significantly differing assessments <strong>of</strong> the effects <strong>of</strong> the firm's<br />

activities. While economic sociology for example defines value creation in the context<br />

<strong>of</strong> the wider society <strong>and</strong> the firm's environment, strategic management more narrowly<br />

focuses on the value creation for the firm itself under the aspect <strong>of</strong> competitive<br />

advantage. In our previous description <strong>of</strong> the firm's action parameters to mitigate its<br />

local exposure in section 4.8, we have argued from the perspective <strong>of</strong> the firm in its<br />

context under a broader <strong>and</strong> a longer term view regarding the targets <strong>of</strong> value creation.<br />

<strong>The</strong>rein the local firm addresses its various stakeholders through its embedding<br />

capabilities, consequently creating value “in many different ways for many different<br />

targets, including earnings for owners, pay for employees, benefits for customers, <strong>and</strong><br />

taxes for society” (Lepak, Smith, & Taylor, 2007: 185). Thus, we have argued, the<br />

firm is able to increase its organisational legitimacy, which in turn supports the firm in<br />

its value creation <strong>and</strong> generation <strong>of</strong> rents for its sustained survival.<br />

Link to research framework. Turning to the output variable within our framework (cf.<br />

Figure 4-16), our underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> value creation more narrowly considers the rents<br />

which the firm is able to create <strong>and</strong> retain for itself, as discussed within the RBV 69 .<br />

This firm-centred perspective therefore disregards value-creating effects <strong>of</strong> the firm's<br />

activities on the firm's various stakeholders. Rather, it focuses on the value the firm<br />

creates through its activities for rent generation <strong>and</strong> for its sustained livelihood.<br />

(2) Market (exchange-based) versus use value (resource-based). Two essentially<br />

different approaches need to be distinguished with regard to the conceptualisation <strong>of</strong><br />

value: Exchange value reflects the power <strong>of</strong> the good to purchase other goods,<br />

69 See also Mahoney (2001), who terms the RBV a theory <strong>of</strong> firm rents.<br />

165


166<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

objectively determined by the market. It is “the monetary amount realised at a single<br />

point in time when the exchange <strong>of</strong> the good takes place” (C. Bowman & Ambrosini,<br />

2000: 3). <strong>The</strong> other approach, known as use value 70 centres on the utility <strong>of</strong> a resource<br />

or good, essentially being a subjectively perceived value. With regard to our research<br />

framework, particularly the latter underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> value is relevant, whose<br />

conceptualisations will be discussed hereafter.<br />

Use value may be understood from the firm's internal perspective as the resources'<br />

utility to the owner (Barney, 1996), or from the customer's perspective, whereby<br />

resource value is linked to perceived customer value (Amit & Schoemaker, 1993; C.<br />

Bowman & Ambrosini, 2000; Collis & Montgomery, 1995). Use value, from the<br />

resource owner's perspective does not rely on the existence <strong>of</strong> a market to establish the<br />

resource's (exchange) value. It is the result <strong>of</strong> internal processes, through which the<br />

firm generates economic rent with the help <strong>of</strong> its resources <strong>and</strong> capabilities (Amit &<br />

Schoemaker, 1993). More specifically, economic rents are created <strong>and</strong> also protected<br />

through managerial decisions on the development <strong>of</strong> strategic assets. Resources <strong>and</strong><br />

capabilities therefore are valuable to the extent that they reduce a firm's costs or<br />

increase its revenue above the level if it had to do without the resource (Barney, 1996),<br />

<strong>and</strong> as far as they enable the firm to exploit opportunities <strong>and</strong> to neutralise threats in a<br />

firm’s environment (Barney, 1991).<br />

As illustrated in Figure 4-17, the firm therefore creates value through its combination<br />

<strong>of</strong> superior resources <strong>and</strong> capabilities, i.e. “the actions <strong>of</strong> organisational members, who<br />

combine to transform the use values that the organisation has acquired” (C. Bowman<br />

& Ambrosini, 2000: 5). <strong>The</strong>reby, it lowers its costs or increases the resource's benefits,<br />

consequently augmenting the latter's use value, i.e. the economic rents as returns to a<br />

factor in excess <strong>of</strong> its opportunity costs (Peteraf & Barney, 2003). As a by-product, it<br />

creates competitive advantage, i.e. the ability to create relatively more economic value,<br />

ultimately creating rent by employing its critical resources more effectively <strong>and</strong><br />

efficiently than it would be the case in the next best alternative.<br />

Superior critical<br />

resources &<br />

capabilities<br />

Firm costs �<br />

<strong>and</strong>/or customer<br />

benefits �<br />

Use value �<br />

firm-internal <strong>and</strong>/or<br />

customer perceived<br />

Figure 4-17: Conception <strong>of</strong> use value creation 71<br />

Competitive<br />

advantage �<br />

Residual value �<br />

i.e. firm margin<br />

Rent �<br />

70 Value <strong>of</strong> use has been first described by Adam Smith in his seminal work '<strong>The</strong> Wealth <strong>of</strong> Nations'<br />

(1776). Defined as the utility <strong>of</strong> a particular object, it is a pre-requisite to any exchange value.<br />

71 On the basis <strong>of</strong> Peteraf <strong>and</strong> Barney (2003).


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

<strong>The</strong> customer-centred conceptualisation bases on the customer's willingness to pay a<br />

price premium, which results in rent for the firm. As Priem (2001) clarifies, this<br />

conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> use value does not pertain to value created by the firm, but to<br />

consumer surplus as the difference between the customer's perceived value <strong>and</strong> the<br />

exchange value. <strong>The</strong> same is true, when looking at the focal firm as a buyer: “whether<br />

a firm captures resources cheaply or not influences that firm's margin; it does not<br />

influence the creation <strong>of</strong> use value by the firm's product” (ibid.: 500).<br />

Link to research framework. In our research framework, both notions <strong>of</strong> use value are<br />

relevant: while the customer-centred notion relates to the rent which the firm captures<br />

by increasing the perceived value <strong>of</strong> its products, the firm-centred use-value covers the<br />

value creating activities inside the firm through intelligent accumulation, combination,<br />

<strong>and</strong> exploitation <strong>of</strong> resources, which may create value which is not perceived by the<br />

end-customer, but which increases the rent <strong>of</strong> the firm, for instance through efficiency<br />

gains. <strong>The</strong> first-mentioned notion stresses the importance <strong>of</strong> leveraging resources to<br />

develop capabilities with value-creating potential, which allow the firm to generate<br />

rent by using those capabilities in the marketplace. To create value for its customers,<br />

the firm's “leveraging processes are critical in matching the firm’s internal capabilities<br />

with conditions in its external environment” (Sirmon, Hitt, & Irel<strong>and</strong>, 2007: 283).<br />

Complementarily, the latter approach is particularly relevant with regard to the<br />

research object's asset specificity <strong>and</strong> the resulting lack <strong>of</strong> market value for significant<br />

parts <strong>of</strong> its resources. <strong>The</strong>refore, UCFs may likely engage in activities which have no<br />

effect on the customer's value perception, <strong>and</strong> which are independent <strong>of</strong> exogenous<br />

factors 72 while creating value <strong>and</strong> rents for the firm.<br />

(3) <strong>The</strong> value <strong>of</strong> real options. Through the options lens, a firm's strategy represents a<br />

process <strong>of</strong> choices for organisational resource-investments, i.e. options (E. Bowman &<br />

Hurry, 1993). <strong>The</strong>se options incorporate strategic flexibility to the firm <strong>and</strong> therefore<br />

have an inherent use value. Because there is a time span between making an<br />

investment decision <strong>and</strong> the actual implementation, the value <strong>of</strong> an investment might<br />

change as the business environment changes, or as additional options <strong>and</strong> alternatives<br />

appear. If the firm is able keep an option open (i.e. delaying the investment decision)<br />

its decision-making basis improves due to reduced uncertainty. <strong>The</strong>reby the firm is<br />

able to reduce its investment risk, having better intelligence on the investment's<br />

opportunity costs. Thus, an options' view allows for the integration <strong>of</strong> inter-project <strong>and</strong><br />

72 See also Peteraf & Barney (2003): 312f.<br />

167


168<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

inter-temporal (time compression) dimensions, as well as value creation considerations<br />

(Dixit & Pindyck, 1994), which increases the quality <strong>of</strong> informed business decisions.<br />

Real options <strong>and</strong> opportunity costs. Real options, a concept originating from financial<br />

theory, infer the future value <strong>of</strong> today's investments from market prices. Accordingly,<br />

a real option is defined as an investment in physical <strong>and</strong> human assets, that provides<br />

the opportunity to respond to future contingent events, i.e. “rights but not obligations<br />

to take some action in the future” (Dixit & Pindyck, 1995: 105). <strong>The</strong> decision for such<br />

an investment entails the three elements <strong>of</strong> uncertainty, provision <strong>of</strong> future managerial<br />

discretion to exercise when deemed appropriate, <strong>and</strong> irreversibility (Kogut &<br />

Kulatilaka, 2001). Thus, when the firm decides to trigger the investment, it gives up its<br />

option <strong>and</strong> incurs opportunity costs, defined as the value <strong>of</strong> the next-highest-valued<br />

alternative use <strong>of</strong> that resource. Essentially, the firm gives up the possibility to wait<br />

until new relevant information is available, which might impact the value or timing <strong>of</strong><br />

the investment - a cost that should be included in the investment calculation. Since<br />

opportunity costs are very sensitive to uncertainty over future developments, for<br />

instance with regard to an investment's revenue streams, the treatment <strong>of</strong> investments<br />

as options underlines the role <strong>of</strong> risk, but also the value that the option creates.<br />

Link to research framework. Examples for UCFs investment options are their property<br />

rights or concessions for natural resources <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> use, technological knowledge, <strong>and</strong><br />

reputation. In many cases these options are idiosyncratic to the firm <strong>and</strong> path<br />

dependent, i.e. they are built over time <strong>and</strong> thus represent a competitive advantage<br />

other firms cannot build upon. <strong>The</strong>refore, for an overall consideration <strong>of</strong> a firm's value<br />

creation, the value <strong>of</strong> options that it is able to create <strong>and</strong> the opportunity costs <strong>of</strong> its<br />

investment decisions need to be taken into account.<br />

(4) Value creation versus value capture. A key issue in economic exchange pertains<br />

to the question <strong>of</strong> who creates <strong>and</strong> who ultimately captures value. In order to earn<br />

above average returns, it is not sufficient for the firm to create Ricardian rents 73 , since<br />

“the laws that regulate the progress <strong>of</strong> rent are widely different from those which<br />

regulate the progress <strong>of</strong> (ordinary) pr<strong>of</strong>its, <strong>and</strong> seldom operate in the same direction”<br />

(Ricardo, 1821: 34). Different from the creation <strong>of</strong> value, value capture is defined as<br />

“the realisation <strong>of</strong> exchange value by economic actors” (C. Bowman & Ambrosini,<br />

2000: 15), being “determined by the perceived power relationships between buyers<br />

<strong>and</strong> sellers” (ibid.: 1). In other words, value capture occurs when use value is high<br />

while exchange value is low (Lepak et al., 2007).<br />

73 Ricardian rents are extraordinary pr<strong>of</strong>its earned from resources in fixed or limited supply.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Link to research framework. <strong>The</strong> distinction between value creation <strong>and</strong> value capture<br />

is central for our research object. Due to the local exposure <strong>and</strong> the specific<br />

characteristics causing this exposure, UCFs are prone to value expropriation by a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> stakeholders. Our underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> value creation within our research<br />

framework therefore pertains to the value, which the UCF creates <strong>and</strong> is also able to<br />

retain.<br />

Summary. <strong>The</strong> firm creates value, when it is able to synchronise the processes <strong>of</strong> its<br />

resource management such, as to achieve a difference between the firm’s costs <strong>and</strong> the<br />

price paid by consumers for its products or services. <strong>The</strong>se processes are affected by<br />

the environmental context, in which the firm operates (Sirmon et al., 2007). On the<br />

basis <strong>of</strong> existing research, the conceptual scope <strong>of</strong> value creation underlying the<br />

proposed framework is summarised as follows:<br />

Conceptualisation issues Underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> value creation within framework<br />

(1) System boundary <strong>The</strong> unit <strong>of</strong> analysis is the firm (within a single geographical<br />

market). Value creation concentrates on the value effects for the<br />

firm, excluding value creation effects for its stakeholders, the<br />

economy or society as a whole.<br />

(2) Use value Value is created by the firm's internal activities, its capabilities in<br />

the accumulation, combination, <strong>and</strong> exploitation <strong>of</strong> resources, but<br />

also through its capabilities to get the consumer to perceive a high<br />

use value <strong>of</strong> the firms' products in order to generate rents.<br />

(3) Value <strong>of</strong> real options <strong>The</strong> value <strong>of</strong> some firm activities can only be adequately<br />

considered, if the related options are included <strong>and</strong> positively<br />

valued, as well as opportunity costs.<br />

(4) Value creation <strong>and</strong> value<br />

capture<br />

Value creation pertains to the value which the UCF creates <strong>and</strong> is<br />

also able to retain.<br />

Table 4-11: Conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> value creation within the research framework<br />

4.9.1 Value creation within the research framework<br />

Following the introduction to the notions <strong>of</strong> firm-level value creation, we<br />

conceptualise use value <strong>and</strong> value creation on the premise <strong>of</strong> our research framework.<br />

<strong>The</strong> use value (utility) <strong>of</strong> a firm's resource consequently is defined as<br />

169


170<br />

Resource use value (t0-tn) = [cash-flows over life-time] (t0-tn) + [option value] (t0-tn)<br />

Where:<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

- 'Resource' means the stocks <strong>of</strong> an available factor owned or controlled by the firm (Amit &<br />

Schoemaker, 1993), including assets <strong>and</strong> capabilities.<br />

- <strong>The</strong> resource-induced cash flows result from efficiency <strong>and</strong> effectiveness 74 improvements,<br />

respectively the avoidance <strong>of</strong> costs through use <strong>of</strong> the resource. <strong>The</strong>se cash flows include the<br />

combinatory value added, as the value <strong>of</strong> the resource within an idiosyncratic resource<br />

bundle. <strong>The</strong> combinatory value added is a perceived value influenced by the firm's<br />

substitution cost <strong>of</strong> the resource.<br />

- <strong>The</strong> value <strong>of</strong> the resource-induced options includes the expected generation <strong>of</strong> rent <strong>and</strong> the<br />

expected avoidance <strong>of</strong> costs from the exploitation <strong>of</strong> opportunities, <strong>and</strong> the value <strong>of</strong><br />

neutralising threats from the firm's environment 75 .<br />

Based on the above value definition, we define the firm's value creation as follows<br />

Value Creation = [resource use value] (t0-tn) - [monetary value] t0 - [development costs] (t0-tn) -<br />

[operating costs] (t0-tn) - [incremental investments] (t0-tn) - [opportunity cost] tx<br />

Where<br />

- Monetary value reflects the exchange value (i.e. the firm's purchasing price), if any.<br />

- Development costs signify the cumulative firm investments in the resource, incurred <strong>and</strong><br />

expected.<br />

- Operating costs are the variable cost to resource exploitation, incurred <strong>and</strong> projected to the<br />

future.<br />

- Incremental investments signify value-preserving or value-enhancing investments in the<br />

resource.<br />

On a time scale, t0 defines the time <strong>of</strong> acquisition <strong>of</strong> the resource, tx refers to the time <strong>of</strong> resource<br />

valuation, <strong>and</strong> tn the expected lifetime <strong>of</strong> the resource, i.e. the year after which the resource ceases<br />

to be valuable to the firm.<br />

From the resource-based point <strong>of</strong> view, resources become more valuable, the more<br />

firm-specific, durable <strong>and</strong> scarce they are (Amit & Schoemaker, 1993). <strong>The</strong> strategic<br />

value <strong>of</strong> such resources <strong>and</strong> capabilities “may not lie merely in the scarcity <strong>of</strong> natural<br />

resources such as l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> oil reserves, but also in the ability to deploy concurrently in<br />

74<br />

In line with Daft's (1983) <strong>and</strong> Barney's (1991) assertion, that valuable firm-controlled resources<br />

need to enable the firm to conceive <strong>of</strong> <strong>and</strong> implement strategies, that improve its efficiency <strong>and</strong><br />

effectiveness.<br />

75<br />

With reference to Barney's (1991: 105) definition <strong>of</strong> a resource being valuable "in the sense that it<br />

exploit[s] opportunities <strong>and</strong>/or neutralises threats in a firm's environment".


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

multiple uses … invisible firm-specific assets as culture, reputation, <strong>and</strong> relationships<br />

with suppliers <strong>and</strong> buyers” (ibid.: 39). <strong>The</strong>ir value contribution therefore may be<br />

partitioned in direct or primary levers, such as increases in operational efficiency or<br />

financial engineering, <strong>and</strong> indirect or secondary levers to value creation, as for<br />

example good reputation <strong>and</strong> relationship management. According to this logic, the<br />

secondary levers create value by positively impacting the primary ones (A. Berg &<br />

Gottschalg, 2005b; Porter, 1985).<br />

Despite the above attempts at clarification, the suggested formula provides only an<br />

indeterminate definition <strong>of</strong> value <strong>and</strong> value creation within the framework 76 . However,<br />

for the purpose <strong>of</strong> identifying areas <strong>of</strong> value creation within the scope <strong>of</strong> our research<br />

question, the suggested definition <strong>and</strong> level <strong>of</strong> detail is useful, even if the firm's levers<br />

for value creation cannot result in quantifiable amounts <strong>and</strong> remain indicative. To<br />

remain within the scope <strong>of</strong> our framework, the discussion <strong>of</strong> value creation remains<br />

focused on the effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> the related local exposure. <strong>The</strong> subsequent<br />

sections aim at unfolding in which fields location-fixed firms, under the influence <strong>of</strong><br />

institutional exposure <strong>and</strong> the moderating impact <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities <strong>of</strong> the<br />

firm's local management, are able to create value.<br />

On the basis <strong>of</strong> our case study research at Zurich Airport, Axpo <strong>and</strong> Holcim, as well as<br />

our literature review, we identified three major areas for value creation <strong>of</strong> UCFs,<br />

which we will elaborate in the subsequent sections:<br />

- value creation through strategic options<br />

- value creation through better investment protection respectively diminished risk<br />

- short-term (direct impact) value creation<br />

4.9.2 Value through strategic options<br />

<strong>The</strong> resource endowment <strong>of</strong> a firm is a decisive factor for its opportunities for future<br />

development, <strong>and</strong> consequently for its strategy formation process. While the existing<br />

firm resources shape its future strategic path, the path ultimately chosen influences the<br />

firm's decisions on its resource investments. From an options perspective, the firm's<br />

resource endowment represents a bundle <strong>of</strong> options for future strategic choice, <strong>and</strong><br />

76 Among others, essential problems, such as attributing a monetary equivalent to intangible valuable<br />

resources (e.g. tacit knowledge or organising routines) to reflect their development costs, remain<br />

unresolved, as does the appropriate valuation <strong>of</strong> options created by the resource. <strong>The</strong> last-mentioned<br />

issue is further complicated by the fact, that at the time <strong>of</strong> assessment some options might not yet be<br />

evident <strong>and</strong> might only develop at a later point in time.<br />

171


172<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

strategy itself is conceived <strong>of</strong> as a portfolio <strong>of</strong> real options. Consequently, the firm's<br />

organisational investments are evaluated according to their ability to create choices (E.<br />

Bowman & Hurry, 1993). <strong>The</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> creating such choices, i.e. strategic<br />

options, is closely related to the firm's environment. <strong>The</strong> value <strong>of</strong> having a bundle <strong>of</strong><br />

options at h<strong>and</strong> tends to increase with management's perceived volatility in the firm's<br />

environment or industry, due to the resulting uncertainty.<br />

What are strategic options. A strategic option is the commitment to relatively modest<br />

expenditures in the present, in order to obtain <strong>and</strong> preserve the opportunity for making<br />

a pr<strong>of</strong>itable investment at some later date. Such “preferential access to future<br />

opportunities” (E. Bowman & Hurry, 1993: 762) includes the option to undertake<br />

activities or to acquire resources (Sanchez, 1993). Options thus incur costs today for<br />

unknowable future streams <strong>of</strong> value, respectively their value can only be assumed ex<br />

ante, while their real value is to be determined ex post. Importantly, options not only<br />

preserve flexibility with hindsight to concrete future projects <strong>and</strong> ventures, but also<br />

increase the firm's scope for action for some undefined future eventualities. <strong>The</strong>y<br />

represent speculative investments with limited <strong>and</strong> known sunk costs, that may<br />

facilitate the firm's value creation activities upon triggering the option. <strong>The</strong> possession<br />

<strong>of</strong> a bundle <strong>of</strong> options serves two objectives: (1) the advantageous positioning <strong>of</strong> the<br />

firm to exploit emerging opportunities, such as to enable future firm development, <strong>and</strong><br />

(2) the protection from the downside risks, e.g. through institutional exposure,<br />

contained in already effected investments (cf. section 4.9.3). Since the value <strong>of</strong> options<br />

changes with a changing firm environment, the development <strong>and</strong> assessment <strong>of</strong> real<br />

options must be ongoing, in order to make effective use <strong>of</strong> the options approach.<br />

Finding the value-maximising moment to trigger the option, consequently requires a<br />

thorough tracking <strong>of</strong> the evolving circumstances.<br />

Options from the firm's embedding capabilities. With reference to our research<br />

framework, firms are able to create real options through their embedding <strong>and</strong><br />

legitimisation activities (cf. Husted, 2005). By making investments, which are<br />

associated with good corporate citizenship <strong>and</strong> corporate social responsibility, firms<br />

create “opportunities to exp<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> grow in the future” (Kogut, 1991: 21). With the<br />

help <strong>of</strong> these investments <strong>and</strong> activities, the firm establishes a supportive business<br />

environment, which enables it to react flexibly to unexpected changes. <strong>The</strong> thus<br />

created options result in direct <strong>and</strong> indirect benefits to the firm (Burke & Logsdon,<br />

1996). Direct benefits draw from the firm's ability to launch new products <strong>and</strong> services<br />

<strong>and</strong> therefore directly impact its bottom line. An example would be the launch <strong>of</strong> a<br />

socially responsible new business field, as demonstrated by the 'Mi Casa' project <strong>of</strong>


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Holcim Mexico (cf. p.134). Indirect benefits result from investments in the firm's<br />

invisible assets <strong>and</strong> are thus less tangible, since they - in line with Berg <strong>and</strong> Gottschalg<br />

(2005b) - create value by positively leveraging the direct ones. Possible indirect<br />

advantages from such options are, for example, facilitated administrative processes in<br />

business development projects, less exposure to regulatory discretion, or faster <strong>and</strong><br />

less damaging mastery <strong>of</strong> a corporate crisis. Due to their idiosyncrasy to the firm, such<br />

options come in the form <strong>of</strong> goodwill stocks, which result in unique business<br />

conditions that are not available to the competition.<br />

Indirect benefits from the firm's options cannot easily be measured with regard to their<br />

contributions to the firm's bottom line. <strong>Local</strong> management, sensitive to the needs <strong>and</strong><br />

expectations <strong>of</strong> the firm's environment, creates such indirectly-working options by<br />

strengthening the firm's organisational legitimacy <strong>and</strong> thus accumulating enabling<br />

assets, on which the firm can draw at a later point in time. <strong>The</strong>se enabling assets act as<br />

insurance against unforeseeable events by limiting the firm's downside risks from its<br />

institutional exposure. Furthermore, they are facilitators in business development,<br />

whose value lies in the creation <strong>of</strong> a wider range <strong>of</strong> business options <strong>and</strong> a faster time<br />

to implementation. Neu, Warsame <strong>and</strong> Pedwell (1998: 265) describe both aspects in<br />

respect <strong>of</strong> organisational legitimacy, which “pre-empts product boycotts or other<br />

disruptive actions by external parties. ... By mitigating these potential problems,<br />

organisational legitimacy provides managers with a degree <strong>of</strong> autonomy to decide how<br />

<strong>and</strong> where business will be conducted”. Enabling assets, which are closely related to<br />

the degree <strong>of</strong> the firm's organisational legitimacy, therefore are defined as follows:<br />

Definition <strong>of</strong> enabling assets<br />

Idiosyncratic intangible resources, which the firm accumulates over time with its<br />

stakeholders, as an insurance against unforeseeable events <strong>and</strong> as facilitators in its<br />

business development.<br />

Link to research framework. Options play an important role in determining the<br />

available strategic paths for the UCF, particularly due to the high level <strong>of</strong> uncertainty<br />

resulting from its long planning horizon <strong>and</strong> the exposure towards its public<br />

stakeholders. Since investment decisions, once taken, bind significant financial<br />

resources, with associated opportunity costs, uncertainty <strong>and</strong> dependence, the success<br />

<strong>of</strong> a UCF is fairly path dependent. Consequently, the UCF must be aware <strong>of</strong> the<br />

significance <strong>of</strong> its embedding in the local environment: compared to footloose firms,<br />

UCFs need to be more concerned with their local legitimacy, credibility, <strong>and</strong> their<br />

173


174<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

links with critical local stakeholders. <strong>The</strong> firm's managerial embedding capabilities<br />

thus influence its scope <strong>of</strong> action <strong>and</strong> strategic flexibility in spite <strong>of</strong> the limited spatial<br />

flexibility. <strong>The</strong>y create options to decrease the downside risks from location-fixity <strong>and</strong><br />

the resulting exposure. Employing options thinking therefore provides the UCF with<br />

value creation opportunities <strong>and</strong> competitive edge, with its options portfolio<br />

representing a critical <strong>and</strong> inimitable resource.<br />

In the subsequent paragraphs, the indirect <strong>and</strong> intangible effects <strong>of</strong> the firm's options<br />

will be briefly discussed, which leads us to the formulation <strong>of</strong> two further propositions<br />

pertaining to our research object.<br />

Insurance against unforeseeable events. Organisational crises are “specific,<br />

unexpected <strong>and</strong> non-routine events or series <strong>of</strong> events that create high levels <strong>of</strong><br />

uncertainty <strong>and</strong> threaten or are perceived to threaten an organisations' high priority<br />

goals” (Seeger, Sellnow, & Ulmer, 1998: 233). Research has shown, that in case <strong>of</strong><br />

such crises, firms with a reputation to behave in socially responsible ways are able to<br />

draw on their accumulated enabling assets, <strong>and</strong> benefit from a faster <strong>and</strong> less damaging<br />

recovery (Husted, 2005). <strong>The</strong> firm's embedding capabilities are an effective way to<br />

'insure' our research object with a goodwill option that enables it to recover in case <strong>of</strong><br />

an unexpected event.<br />

Proposition 13<br />

<strong>The</strong> effective use <strong>of</strong> the UCF's embedding capabilities leads to an accumulation <strong>of</strong><br />

enabling assets, which help the firm to master unexpected threatening events faster,<br />

less costly <strong>and</strong> with less damage.<br />

Facilitators in business development. In a dynamic industry environment, a firm's<br />

success depends on its ability to adapt. Such strategic flexibility might require the firm<br />

to adjust its existing asset base, to introduce emerging technologies, to exp<strong>and</strong> into<br />

new businesses or develop new products, not to mention the development <strong>of</strong> new sites<br />

in the form <strong>of</strong> Green- or Brownfield projects. Depending on the firm's relations with<br />

its local environment, such extensions are <strong>of</strong>ten slowed down or even prevented by<br />

stakeholder resistance, regulatory hurdles <strong>and</strong> political processes. Getting the local<br />

administration's go-ahead for investments beyond regulatory requirements may turn<br />

into a hurdle race, leading to delays, limiting conditions to implementation, or<br />

ab<strong>and</strong>onment <strong>of</strong> the investment altogether. From the options perspective, the firm's<br />

possibilities to avoid such cumbersome <strong>and</strong> costly experiences depend - inter alia - on


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

its ability to accumulate enabling assets, the eventual use <strong>of</strong> which is comparable to<br />

the exercise <strong>of</strong> an option.<br />

Thus, over the lifetime <strong>of</strong> a site’s installed assets the firm's local management goes<br />

through phases <strong>of</strong> differing intensity in their embedding efforts (see also section 6.3.1),<br />

through phases <strong>of</strong> creating, <strong>of</strong> keeping <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> triggering options for the firm's<br />

sustained livelihood. Depending on its track-record <strong>of</strong> investing in its organisational<br />

legitimacy <strong>and</strong> accumulation <strong>of</strong> enabling assets, it is rewarded with a facilitated <strong>and</strong><br />

cost-saving business development process.<br />

Proposition 14<br />

<strong>The</strong> creation <strong>and</strong> accumulation <strong>of</strong> enabling assets allows UCFs to shorten their time to<br />

implementation for major infrastructure-related investments, as well as other business<br />

development activities.<br />

Example: Speed track to regulatory approval through pro-active embedding efforts<br />

'Linthal 2015' represents the largest investment in Axpo's history (cf. example p.115). With a total<br />

investment <strong>of</strong> CHF 2.1bn it is also the largest Swiss hydropower project to date. Kraftwerke Linth<br />

Limmern AG (KLL), Axpo's local subsidiary, historically has a strong presence in the Linthal region<br />

since 1957, when it started with the construction <strong>of</strong> the valley's first hydropower plant. In 1965 it<br />

completed the high pressure storage plant 'Linth-Limmern', including the Limmern reservoir. From<br />

this time onwards, KLL became a major economic factor in the Linthal region. Due to its continued<br />

local commitment <strong>and</strong> its value creation for the surrounding communities, KLL was able to<br />

accumulate stocks <strong>of</strong> enabling assets, which it drew upon in its 'Linthal 2015' project. Based on the<br />

trust <strong>and</strong> reputation <strong>of</strong> KLL, the positive reputational spillover effects from the corporate parent Axpo,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the promise <strong>of</strong> even more economic benefits to the region, the local stakeholders supported the<br />

project from its beginning. <strong>The</strong> result was a trade-<strong>of</strong>f between economic development <strong>and</strong><br />

environmental sustainability which was acceptable to all relevant parties. Thus, from the start <strong>of</strong> the<br />

stakeholder negotiations in March 2005 it took the company only 54 months to find a widely endorsed<br />

solution <strong>and</strong> to obtain a construction permit. Due to the trusting relationship, Axpo was also able to<br />

make best use <strong>of</strong> the approval period, setting up the construction site to be ready for a speedy kick-<strong>of</strong>f<br />

<strong>of</strong> the construction activities.<br />

Example: Community Advisory Panel at Holcim's Albox Plant, Spain<br />

When Holcim communicated its plans for building a waste pre-treatment site in Albox, Spain (cf.<br />

Example, p.144), the project was met with significant local opposition. Holcim therefore engaged in a<br />

stakeholder dialogue right from the project's beginning. Key platform in this dialogue was the CAP,<br />

which the firm established to regularly inform its stakeholders <strong>and</strong> to encourage their constructive<br />

engagement in the project. Importantly, Holcim managed to convince the mayor <strong>of</strong> Albox <strong>and</strong><br />

representatives <strong>of</strong> other local authorities, as well as environmental <strong>and</strong> community groups to join the<br />

175


176<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

CAP. Furthermore, Holcim's organisational legitimacy was increased through the appointment <strong>of</strong> a<br />

leading member <strong>of</strong> the NGO 'Ecologistas en Acción' as secretary to the CAP. As a local opinion<br />

maker, the latter described the role <strong>of</strong> the Albox CAP as “an important tool for 'greening' the town<br />

through educational projects” 77 <strong>and</strong> a means to further ensure transparency <strong>of</strong> the operation. Through<br />

the combination <strong>of</strong> these steps, Holcim was able to build enabling assets over a short period <strong>of</strong> time,<br />

which provided it with the option to continue its project implementation with the cooperation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

affected stakeholders. Had Holcim not succeeded in gaining the support <strong>of</strong> the local environment, its<br />

time to implementation might have been considerably longer, with resulting consequences on its<br />

business plans.<br />

4.9.3 Value through risk decrease<br />

Risk is defined as uncertainty about outcomes or events, particularly with respect to<br />

the future (Miller & Bromiley, 1990). Risk research originally started from finance<br />

theory, mainly emphasising the risks <strong>of</strong> efficient markets from an investor's<br />

perspective, i.e. the ex-post market judgment <strong>of</strong> financial risks. By contrast, risk<br />

conceptions within management science take a firm-internal point <strong>of</strong> view, concerned<br />

with the relationships among risk, superior levels <strong>of</strong> performance, the roles <strong>of</strong><br />

managers <strong>and</strong> their (ex-ante) decisions, <strong>and</strong> the organisation. In addition they view<br />

firms in the context <strong>of</strong> their industry <strong>and</strong> environment (Bromiley, Miller, & Rau, 2001;<br />

Ruefli, Collins, & Lacugna, 1999).<br />

Link to research framework. Due to their location-fixity UCFs are confronted with<br />

a variety <strong>of</strong> risks over the length <strong>of</strong> their projected business activity. As has been<br />

discussed before, not only political <strong>and</strong> regulatory challenges from the nature <strong>of</strong> their<br />

business, but also the risk exposure due to their externalities <strong>and</strong> the resulting visibility<br />

to their immediate environment <strong>and</strong> the public in general are remarkable. A disregard<br />

<strong>of</strong> this exposure increases the firm's risks by provoking a conversion <strong>of</strong> stakeholders'<br />

implicit claims into explicit ones in the future. Ignoring implicit stakeholder claims<br />

<strong>and</strong> expectations from the local environment ultimately could lead to the withdrawal <strong>of</strong><br />

local support, i.e. the loss <strong>of</strong> the firm's 'licence to operate'. <strong>The</strong> risks related to such a<br />

loss <strong>of</strong> support range from labour issues, stakeholder boycotts, to the threat <strong>of</strong> more<br />

restrictive governmental regulation, or even the withdrawal <strong>of</strong> the firm's concession, if<br />

it does not show enough pro-active engagement in social <strong>and</strong> environmental issues. On<br />

the other h<strong>and</strong>, being sensitive to such risks <strong>and</strong> investing in activities to decrease<br />

them creates value to the firm <strong>and</strong> provides it with more stability in its business<br />

outlook. Our empirical research has led us to the identification <strong>of</strong> two main areas,<br />

77 Berbel Granados, M., cited in: Holcim Spain (n.d.). Community advisory panel in Albox - Holcim<br />

Spain. Retrieved 14.12.2009, from www.holcim.com/CORP/EN/id/73138/mod//page/editorial.html.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

where management's embedding capabilities contribute to a decrease in UCFs risks:<br />

regulatory discretion, pertaining to risks from the firm's exposure towards public<br />

institutions <strong>and</strong> politics, <strong>and</strong> non-recovery <strong>of</strong> invested capital, which relates to the risks<br />

<strong>of</strong> not recovering the firm's sunk costs. Both aspects will be further discussed in the<br />

subsequent paragraphs.<br />

Regulatory discretion & institutional risks. In existing research a number <strong>of</strong> studies<br />

identified a link between firms' activities as good corporate citizens <strong>and</strong> business risk,<br />

respectively a positive correlation between CSR <strong>and</strong> stakeholder engagement, <strong>and</strong><br />

pr<strong>of</strong>it variability (e.g. E. Bowman, 1980; Waddock & Graves, 1997; Wood, 1991) .<br />

According to their observations, firms engaging in socially responsible activities<br />

thereby incorporate organising principles that are surprise-avoiding, <strong>and</strong> which help it<br />

to anticipate <strong>and</strong> reduce potential sources <strong>of</strong> business risk (Orlitzky & Benjamin,<br />

2001). In the case <strong>of</strong> UCI, a great concern to firms' long-term survival <strong>and</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>itability<br />

is the prospect <strong>of</strong> recovering their sunk costs within reasonable time. As has been<br />

discussed before (cf. p. 108f), these prospects are directly related to regulatory <strong>and</strong><br />

political risks, which entail many forms <strong>of</strong> appropriation <strong>of</strong> the firm's quasi-rents.<br />

Spiller <strong>and</strong> Tommasi (2005: 517f) pointedly summarise the argument:<br />

[T]he overarching problem driving the regulation <strong>of</strong> utilities, whether public or<br />

private, … is how to limit governmental opportunism, understood as the incentives<br />

politicians have to expropriate – once the investments are made – the utilities’<br />

quasi-rents, whether under private or public ownership, so as to garner political<br />

support.<br />

But apart from opportunism-driven risks, there are also risks from other motivations <strong>of</strong><br />

the public stakeholders, as for example from the motivation <strong>of</strong> regulators, who are in<br />

pursuit <strong>of</strong> their public mission by means <strong>of</strong> regulation <strong>and</strong> enforcement there<strong>of</strong>. This<br />

m<strong>and</strong>ate equips them with a degree <strong>of</strong> discretion to set their agendas, as well as to<br />

interpret their imposed rules.<br />

Since a firm's reputation to some extent influences the actions <strong>of</strong> a regulator, the<br />

degree <strong>of</strong> a regulator's attention <strong>and</strong> his adopted remedies in case <strong>of</strong> poor compliance<br />

are “framed” by the firm's behaviour, attitude <strong>and</strong> efforts towards correction in case <strong>of</strong><br />

a problem (Neu et al., 1998). <strong>The</strong>refore, the firm's overall legitimising activities may<br />

contribute significantly to decrease its institutional risks. With regard to the firm's<br />

structural (economic) embedding capabilities its good internal governance,<br />

transparency towards the public, the sharing <strong>of</strong> created value with the local<br />

environment to increase overall welfare, as well as its mechanisms <strong>of</strong> mutual lock-in<br />

177


178<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

contribute to reduce the firm's exposure to politically motivated action. In addition,<br />

such exemplary corporate behaviour helps the firm to build social capital: Pertaining to<br />

the firm's relational (social) embedding capabilities, the cultivation <strong>and</strong> maintenance <strong>of</strong><br />

good relationships with its public stakeholders help to build mutual trust. In addition<br />

the firm's continuous efforts towards reputation-building (supported through its<br />

embedding activities on the structural dimension) <strong>and</strong> its visible adaptation to the local<br />

environment serve the accumulation <strong>of</strong> goodwill stocks <strong>and</strong> public approval. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

concerted activities aim at rendering self-interested opportunistic behaviour from<br />

public stakeholders unattractive, since a high public legitimacy <strong>of</strong> the firm limits the<br />

political capital to be gained. A favourable public opinion as a buffer against<br />

institutional risks is particularly important in political systems with frequent changes,<br />

where relationship-building with public stakeholders does not render long-term effects.<br />

Thus, building goodwill with the local public(s), but also investing in trusting <strong>and</strong><br />

cooperative relationships with the public stakeholders, increases the firm's chances on<br />

generating <strong>and</strong> keeping rent-creating revenues. Possible beneficial effects are fewer<br />

opportunistically motivated activities, such as re-distributional action by the<br />

government; formal approval <strong>of</strong> prices above the firm's long-term average costs; <strong>and</strong><br />

from a public policy perspective, the general forestalling <strong>of</strong> unfavourable discretionary<br />

regulatory activities.<br />

Proposition 15<br />

<strong>The</strong> UCF's effective use <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities creates value by reducing the risk<br />

<strong>of</strong> unfavourable regulatory <strong>and</strong> political discretion.<br />

Non-recovery <strong>of</strong> invested capital. <strong>The</strong> UCF's risk <strong>of</strong> not recovering its sunk costs is<br />

closely related to its institutional risks. <strong>The</strong> risks from regulatory, political <strong>and</strong><br />

administrative discretion can have immediate effects on the firm, but they also may<br />

impact the asset's amortisation period, impairing the firm's cash flows for its whole<br />

period <strong>of</strong> commitment for which it has received a public concession. Regulatory <strong>and</strong><br />

institutional risks to the recovery <strong>of</strong> investments range from restrictions on the firm's<br />

pricing flexibility (e.g. regulated charges or price caps), additional conditions to<br />

operation (e.g. requests for further investments, or with regard to purchasing or<br />

employment patterns), restrictions on the movement <strong>of</strong> capital, public take-over <strong>of</strong> the<br />

firm's assets with below-value compensation, or outright expropriation.<br />

Through a decrease <strong>of</strong> rent-appropriation risks firms gain more scope for action by


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

- freeing managerial capacities from political <strong>and</strong> regulatory struggles, which<br />

may be devoted to the business again<br />

- applying economic reasoning to investment decisions, thus being able to invest<br />

the optimal level <strong>of</strong> capital for mid- <strong>and</strong> long-term infrastructure development,<br />

as opposed to notorious underinvestment due to expropriation fears<br />

- increasing the quality <strong>of</strong> products <strong>and</strong> services through higher investments in<br />

value-conserving maintenance, due to lower expropriation fears<br />

- allowing a long-term business outlook regarding investments whose<br />

amortisation period exceeds the concession period, due to reduced uncertainty<br />

<strong>The</strong>se arguments are summarised in the following proposition:<br />

Proposition 16<br />

By effectively employing its embedding capabilities, the UCF is able to reduce the risk<br />

to not recover its sunk costs, respectively to increase the probability <strong>of</strong> capital<br />

recovery.<br />

Example: Bangalore International Airport's struggle with the User Development Fee<br />

When the Bangalore International Airport (BIA) opened in June 2008, the airport had an evidenced<br />

right to levy a User Development Fee (UDF), the amount <strong>of</strong> which being subject to approval <strong>of</strong> the<br />

relevant authorities (see also p.117). Although the airport operator h<strong>and</strong>ed in its request <strong>and</strong> all<br />

relevant materials before airport opening, it took more than six months into airport operations to<br />

obtain an <strong>of</strong>ficial response, which in addition only granted a proportion <strong>of</strong> the requested fee to be<br />

levied. In a retrospective analysis <strong>of</strong> the reasons for such a delay, the operator became aware, that<br />

while it focused on tight construction management <strong>of</strong> the greenfield airport <strong>and</strong> on the planning <strong>of</strong> an<br />

operationally smooth start-up, it possibly did not invest enough resources in the management <strong>of</strong> its<br />

relationships with the public stakeholders. Given the high relevance <strong>of</strong> public authorities <strong>and</strong><br />

politicians in the Indian context, this neglect became felt, when the political issues around the User<br />

Development Fee would have required strong working relations with them. As a result, the<br />

management <strong>of</strong> the airport operator was not heard, when it tried to lobby for its contractual right.<br />

When the airport finally was allowed to levy the fee, it had irrecoverably lost six months <strong>of</strong> fee<br />

revenues, which it would have needed for its debt servicing, cost recovery <strong>and</strong> ultimately for the<br />

funding <strong>of</strong> future expansion projects.<br />

Today, the operator has an excellent political affairs management in place, which monitors impending<br />

issues <strong>and</strong> which cultivates strong working relationships with the relevant decision <strong>and</strong> opinion<br />

makers. <strong>The</strong>reby it is able to h<strong>and</strong>le issues faster, more effectively <strong>and</strong> with less risks <strong>and</strong> costs. In<br />

addition, members <strong>of</strong> the management board are more sensitised towards paying regular courtesy<br />

visits to key decision makers, <strong>and</strong> get involved early in the management <strong>of</strong> political issues.<br />

179


180<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

4.9.4 Short-term (direct impact) value creation<br />

In addition to the mostly indirect value-creation effects from strategic options <strong>and</strong><br />

from the decrease <strong>of</strong> institutional risks, the UCF's effective h<strong>and</strong>ling <strong>of</strong> its local<br />

exposure also has beneficial short-term effects which directly contribute to its bottomline.<br />

Based on insights from our case studies, as well the review <strong>of</strong> literature, we were<br />

able to identify the following main categories <strong>of</strong> direct levers to the firm's valuecreation:<br />

the reduction <strong>of</strong> transaction costs, increases in operational efficiency, as well<br />

as in financial efficiency, <strong>and</strong> the exploitation <strong>of</strong> positive externalities.<br />

Reduction in transaction costs. In the neoclassical economists' world <strong>of</strong> perfect<br />

markets, actors are perfectly informed at no cost, contracts are complete, <strong>and</strong> therefore<br />

no transaction costs exist. In the real world, however, economic actors experience<br />

imperfect information <strong>and</strong> bounded rationality, which - in combination with<br />

opportunism, environmental complexity <strong>and</strong> asset specificity - result in transaction<br />

costs. <strong>The</strong>se transaction costs consist <strong>of</strong> search <strong>and</strong> information costs, bargaining <strong>and</strong><br />

decision costs, monitoring <strong>and</strong> enforcement costs (Robins, 1987) <strong>and</strong> occur “when a<br />

good or service is transferred across a technologically separable interface. One stage <strong>of</strong><br />

activity terminates <strong>and</strong> another begins” (O Williamson, 1981: 552). Likening<br />

transactions to a well-functioning machine, Williamson (ibid.) compares them to<br />

frictions in the mechanism, caused by disharmony between the parties,<br />

misunderst<strong>and</strong>ings <strong>and</strong> conflicts, leading to delays, breakdowns, <strong>and</strong> other<br />

malfunctions. <strong>The</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> these malfunctions on a firm's operations <strong>and</strong> bottom-line<br />

may be considerable. Not only do they result in costs, they may also turn the firm's<br />

relations with transaction partners more rigid, slowing down transactions' realisation<br />

<strong>and</strong> making later adaptations more difficult (cf. p.137). <strong>The</strong>refore, “an important<br />

source <strong>of</strong> economic value creation stems from reduction <strong>of</strong> the dissipation <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

value in the exchange process” (Asher, Mahoney, & Mahoney, 2005: 11).<br />

This can be accomplished with the help <strong>of</strong> the firm's embedding capabilities, thus<br />

decreasing transaction costs <strong>and</strong> the need for formal governance mechanisms, <strong>and</strong><br />

freeing resources for other productive uses (Gössling, 2004; Uzzi, 1999). In addition,<br />

the reduced transactional uncertainty opens up opportunities for the exchange <strong>of</strong> goods<br />

<strong>and</strong> services that are difficult to price or enforce contractually (Uzzi, 1996). Depending<br />

on the firm's transaction partner <strong>and</strong> the type <strong>of</strong> interaction, different aspects <strong>of</strong> the<br />

firm's embedding capabilities are needed to reduce its transaction costs. Furthermore,<br />

different types <strong>of</strong> transaction costs are involved. Table 4-12 provides an overview on<br />

the possible advantageous effects <strong>of</strong> the firm's embedding capabilities on transaction


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

costs with its relevant stakeholders. For that purpose, three basic types <strong>of</strong> interactions<br />

are distinguished - frequent, infrequent, <strong>and</strong> no direct exchange.<br />

private stakeholders<br />

public stakeholders<br />

stakeholder no direct<br />

exchange<br />

local community less litigation<br />

<strong>and</strong> hold-up<br />

civilian interest<br />

groups<br />

less litigation<br />

<strong>and</strong> hold-up<br />

one-<strong>of</strong>f (market)<br />

transaction,<br />

infrequent exchange<br />

suppliers improved purchasing<br />

conditions based on<br />

the firm's reputation<br />

customers improved selling<br />

conditions based on<br />

the firm's reputation<br />

service partners<br />

long-term relation,<br />

frequent exchange<br />

trust-based increase in<br />

flexibility & adaptability,<br />

less formal private<br />

ordering solutions, i.e.<br />

reduced cost for contract<br />

specification, negotiation,<br />

management & monitoring<br />

employees higher loyalty, less<br />

turnover, interest<br />

alignment between firm &<br />

employee<br />

public<br />

shareholder<br />

government /<br />

political<br />

dimension<br />

reduced<br />

incentives for<br />

politicallymotivated<br />

adverse<br />

activities<br />

reduced cost <strong>of</strong> regulatory<br />

intervention, better interest<br />

alignment, early<br />

recognition & action<br />

regarding public policy<br />

expectations<br />

regulator early recognition &<br />

correction <strong>of</strong> regulatory<br />

complaints, reduced costs<br />

from unforeseen regulatory<br />

action<br />

Table 4-12: Type <strong>of</strong> exchange <strong>and</strong> effects on firm transaction costs<br />

181


182<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Skilful deployment <strong>of</strong> the firm's embedding capabilities, particularly its relational<br />

ones, may reduce its transaction costs on the basis <strong>of</strong> a favourable reputation. This<br />

effect certainly applies to parties, with whom the firm infrequently transacts, <strong>and</strong> to<br />

which it thus is able to signal trustworthiness. Even more importantly, with regard to<br />

long-st<strong>and</strong>ing transaction partners the firm is able to lower its transaction costs as<br />

follows: if trusting stakeholder relations are related to socially responsible firm<br />

comportment, they lead to more efficient contracting <strong>and</strong> “can create an organisational<br />

expectation <strong>of</strong> altruism, in which opportunistic politicking has no place <strong>and</strong>, thus, no<br />

costs associated with it” (Orlitzky & Benjamin, 2001: 374). <strong>The</strong>refore, “high levels <strong>of</strong><br />

social capital reduce transaction costs … <strong>and</strong> ultimately, enhance a firm's<br />

performance” (Branco & Rodrigues, 2006: 119), while creating strategically valuable<br />

relational resources <strong>and</strong> competitive advantage.<br />

Operational Efficiency. With the objective to ensure pr<strong>of</strong>itable long-term survival,<br />

firms continuously strive to improve the efficiency <strong>of</strong> their resource deployment.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se resources include<br />

all assets, capabilities, organisational processes, firm attributes, information,<br />

knowledge, etc. controlled by a firm that enable the firm to conceive <strong>of</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

implement strategies that improve its efficiency <strong>and</strong> effectiveness. (Daft, 1983, as<br />

cited in Barney, 1991: 101)<br />

Value-creating efficiency gains are accomplished through effects <strong>of</strong> scale, measured as<br />

average cost per unit <strong>of</strong> production, effects <strong>of</strong> scope, defined as the effect on efficiency<br />

<strong>of</strong> the range <strong>of</strong> different activities, or effects <strong>of</strong> experience, i.e. the effect <strong>of</strong> cumulative<br />

production over time (Nooteboom, 2007). In some cases economies <strong>of</strong> scope or scale<br />

are also related to the presence <strong>of</strong> fixed interval costs, where the production <strong>of</strong> a good<br />

or service becomes economically feasible only beyond a defined minimum level, e.g.<br />

due to minimum setup costs <strong>of</strong> a production facility. Such step-fixed interval costs<br />

apply to most utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-bound industries, illustrated by the fix capacity<br />

intervals <strong>of</strong> runways, airport or seaport terminals, nuclear power plants, sewage plants,<br />

or in oil extraction.<br />

<strong>The</strong> characteristics <strong>of</strong> UCFs make operational efficiency a particularly vital success<br />

factor, notably due to their capital intensity <strong>and</strong> their external limitations (cf. subchapter<br />

3.4.2): from an upstream perspective, many firms face limited availability <strong>of</strong><br />

key resources, as in the cases <strong>of</strong> hydropower or oil production. Downstream, for some<br />

UCF the means to exploit their site's capacity are equally limited. As opposed to<br />

manufacturing industries, which are able to store their manufactured goods or to


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

export them to other markets, many UCI face limits on the dem<strong>and</strong> side due to the<br />

local (<strong>and</strong> sometimes perishable) nature <strong>of</strong> their product. Examples are airports, whose<br />

operation is characterised by peak-times throughout the day, straining their<br />

infrastructure, while for significant periods <strong>of</strong> their operational pattern they run below<br />

their provided capacity. Such an operation is not only expensive due to the slack in<br />

<strong>of</strong>f-peak windows, but puts the airport operator before the choice <strong>of</strong> increasing its<br />

peak-operation efficiency to increase utilisation, versus adding capacity to the airport<br />

which entails costly non-gradual extension intervals. Apart from these resource <strong>and</strong><br />

market constraints, there are other external limitations on capacity instalment or<br />

resource exploitation from the public stakeholders' side, which frame the firm's scope<br />

<strong>of</strong> action. Thus, the combination <strong>of</strong> the costs <strong>of</strong> bound capital, limited discretion in<br />

capacity adjustments, <strong>and</strong> UCFs' effects <strong>of</strong> scale, lead to a considerable lever <strong>of</strong> even<br />

minor resource utilisation improvements on the firm's rent-generation.<br />

In order to maximise resource utilisation before instalment <strong>of</strong> the next capacity<br />

interval 78 , the firm itself has to find creative <strong>and</strong> flexible ways for improvement.<br />

However, in some cases such increases in capacity utilisation require the approval <strong>of</strong><br />

the firm's stakeholders, such as the extension <strong>of</strong> operating hours, which depends on the<br />

UCF's concession arrangements, its externalities, or applicable labour law, <strong>and</strong> might<br />

require other special permissions. Such constraints are also illustrated by the example<br />

<strong>of</strong> the hydropower industry, where environmental concerns <strong>of</strong>ten reduce the plant's<br />

capacity utilisation, due to minimum requirements on residual water. In such cases<br />

those firms will create value, which are able to find an intersection between the needs<br />

resulting from the nature <strong>of</strong> their business <strong>and</strong> the expectations <strong>and</strong> requirements from<br />

their stakeholders. By means <strong>of</strong> the UCF's embedding capabilities, managers have the<br />

ability to accumulate enabling assets that increase the area <strong>of</strong> this intersection <strong>and</strong> thus<br />

to creatively co-create alternative win-win solutions.<br />

Example: Axpo's solution-finding in the Linth Limmern hydropower project<br />

In Axpo's large-scale hydropower project Linth Limmern the firm faced expectations <strong>and</strong> concerns<br />

from a wide range <strong>of</strong> stakeholders. Particularly environmental interest groups were worried about the<br />

impacts <strong>of</strong> such a project on the local ecosystem. Through early involvement <strong>of</strong> the relevant<br />

stakeholders in the project planning <strong>and</strong> through Axpo's interest in underst<strong>and</strong>ing their core concerns<br />

<strong>and</strong> requirements, the parties were soon able to find workable solutions, satisfactory to both sides.<br />

Ultimately, Axpo preserved the project's economic viability <strong>and</strong> planned resource utilisation by<br />

convincing its stakeholders <strong>of</strong> the implementation plans for the increase <strong>of</strong> storage capacity at Lake<br />

78<br />

An option, which is not always available, as for example in hydropower plants, which rely on the<br />

given quantity <strong>of</strong> water available at the site.<br />

183


184<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Mutt, whose natural lake level will be raised by approximately 30 meters. On one h<strong>and</strong>, Axpo<br />

supported the conduct <strong>of</strong> field studies to survey ecological diversity <strong>and</strong> to assess environmental<br />

compatibility. On the other, the firm agreed on environmental compensatory measures, such as the<br />

improvement <strong>of</strong> the fish habitat through various structural <strong>and</strong> procedural adaptations, scenic<br />

appreciation <strong>of</strong> the region, <strong>and</strong> measures to improve fauna <strong>and</strong> flora. Furthermore, its agreement to<br />

ab<strong>and</strong>on the exploitation <strong>of</strong> the Linth gorge, including renaturation <strong>and</strong> an increase in the residual<br />

water volume, finally secured it the support - or at least non-objection - <strong>of</strong> the environmental groups<br />

<strong>and</strong> allowed it to continue with the planned scope <strong>of</strong> the project.<br />

Thus, it can be followed:<br />

Proposition 17<br />

<strong>The</strong> higher the firm's organisational legitimacy, <strong>and</strong> the more credibly it is able to<br />

convey its readiness to search for integrative solutions, the higher the approval by its<br />

stakeholders for, respectively the lower the resistance against its endeavours to<br />

improve efficiency.<br />

Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> financial processes. Management's ability to access financial<br />

markets for sufficient capital, respectively to secure adequate credit lines is essential<br />

for firms which bind significant amounts <strong>of</strong> capital in their infrastructure. In raising<br />

funds for the instalment <strong>of</strong> heavy infrastructure, such as an airport, a railway line, a<br />

full-fledged hospital, or a seaport terminal, small differences in the firm's borrowing<br />

costs can have a significant overall impact. But financing costs are not only influenced<br />

by the firm's capital structure, past performance or future revenue outlooks. <strong>The</strong>y are<br />

also affected by the firm's reputation “shaping the responses <strong>of</strong> external actors,<br />

because they summarise a good deal <strong>of</strong> information about a firm's current position <strong>and</strong><br />

behaviour <strong>and</strong> also its probable future behaviour” (Teece et al., 1997: 521).<br />

As has been outlined before, comportment as a good corporate citizen decreases some<br />

<strong>of</strong> the firm's risks <strong>and</strong> increases its options for future development. In addition, it<br />

positively influences the firm's reputation in financial markets, sending a strong signal<br />

to financial investors <strong>and</strong> lenders. Capital invested in a firm that operates in a stable<br />

local environment, <strong>and</strong> which enjoys stakeholder legitimacy for its activities, has a<br />

lower risk to it (Bansal & Clell<strong>and</strong>, 2004). As research has shown (Goyal & Santa-<br />

Clara, 2003), such lower unsystematic risk increases the probability <strong>of</strong> continued<br />

stable cash flow generation <strong>and</strong> hence, the firm's ability to service debt or to pay<br />

dividends. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, poor regulatory compliance <strong>and</strong> other socially<br />

objectionable behaviour might have spill-over effects on the perceptions <strong>of</strong> other


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

stakeholders. Such comportment might, for example, affect the firm's reputation with<br />

financial investors, which in turn might change their risk perception towards their<br />

investment object, <strong>and</strong> consequently impact the firm's financing costs. Thus, if the<br />

firm's management is able to build a strong reputation <strong>and</strong> to convey its organisational<br />

legitimacy to its investors <strong>and</strong> creditors, the firm has the opportunity to lower its costs<br />

<strong>of</strong> capital (cf. Fombrun et al., 2000), e.g. by receiving a more favourable (i.e. riskadjusted)<br />

credit-rating or a better stock-market valuation. Branco & Rodrigues (2006:<br />

124) argue, that firms which are regarded as socially responsible benefit from their<br />

reputation “by having increased ability to attract capital <strong>and</strong> trading partners”, a<br />

capability critical to UCFs' long-term survival.<br />

Furthermore, other areas for improving the efficiency <strong>of</strong> the firm's financial processes<br />

are its cash management, inventory management, as well as the collection <strong>of</strong><br />

receivables. Also these efficiency issues are linked to management's embedding<br />

capabilities, particularly to the firm's reputation, as well as its perceived<br />

trustworthiness. Stakeholders interacting with the firm, rate it on its competency to<br />

perform according to its obligations <strong>and</strong> agreements (competence trust), as well as its<br />

intentions to do so (goodwill trust) 79 (Nooteboom, 1996). In the firm's endeavours to<br />

decrease its working capital, e.g. by lowering inventory <strong>and</strong> accounts receivables or by<br />

increasing its accounts payables, it depends on the cooperation <strong>of</strong> its stakeholders.<br />

Chances for implementing a high payment discipline rise with the existence <strong>of</strong> trustbased<br />

relations to those customers with whom it is directly interacting. <strong>The</strong> same<br />

applies to inventory management, where trust-based supplier-customer relationships<br />

allow for smaller stocks in the firm's critical resources. <strong>The</strong>refore we further propose:<br />

Proposition 18<br />

<strong>The</strong> UCF's degree <strong>of</strong> local embeddedness <strong>and</strong> organisational legitimacy indirectly<br />

influence its value creation by increasing the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> its financial processes.<br />

Valorisation <strong>of</strong> by-products (exploitation <strong>of</strong> positive externalities). An externality<br />

is present, when there is a divergence between private <strong>and</strong> social cost. More<br />

accurately, the problem <strong>of</strong> externalities is “that private costs (or benefits), which do<br />

influence a resource owner, are not equivalent to the total <strong>of</strong> social costs (or benefits)<br />

associated with the way an owner uses his resources” (Demsetz, 2003: 283). With<br />

regard to economic transactions, an externality is an impact on a party that is not<br />

79 See also section on Trust, p.156f.<br />

185


186<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

directly involved, with the effect that prices do not reflect the full costs or benefits in<br />

production or consumption <strong>of</strong> a product or service. Pertaining to the output variable <strong>of</strong><br />

our research framework, i.e. value creation, we focus on positive externalities which<br />

are created when part <strong>of</strong> the benefit <strong>of</strong> producing a good accrues to a party other than<br />

that which produces it. Since UCFs are significant producers <strong>of</strong> externalities - mostly<br />

negative, but there exist also a range <strong>of</strong> positive ones - they may create value by<br />

capturing essentially negative externalities <strong>and</strong> transforming them into valuable byproducts,<br />

respectively through the valorisation <strong>of</strong> such by-products.<br />

<strong>The</strong> availability <strong>of</strong> these value creation opportunities is partly moderated by the firm's<br />

embedding capabilities, pertaining to its ability to mobilise stakeholder support for<br />

externality-exploiting projects. By credibly developing win-win propositions, which<br />

increase the firm's resource efficiency through additional uses <strong>of</strong> so far 'lost'<br />

externalities, while equally increasing stakeholder's utility through rent-sharing, firms<br />

are able to increase their pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>and</strong> competitiveness. Since projects towards<br />

externality exploitation in most cases depend on the support <strong>of</strong> the local administration<br />

<strong>and</strong> the local community, the firm's reputation, trustworthiness, communication skills,<br />

as well as the value proposition for the stakeholders, are decisive facilitators in<br />

obtaining final approval.<br />

Proposition 19<br />

<strong>The</strong> UCF’s effective use <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities creates value by increasing the<br />

firm's resource efficiency through joint exploitation <strong>of</strong> positive externalities or the<br />

transformation <strong>of</strong> negative externalities into exploitable ones.<br />

<strong>The</strong> subsequent examples illustrate externality exploitation by the chosen case study<br />

objects.<br />

Example: Axpo's long-distance heating <strong>and</strong> gas production<br />

Electricity generation <strong>of</strong>ten is linked with the production <strong>of</strong> unwanted by-products. <strong>The</strong> production <strong>of</strong><br />

nuclear power, for example, creates heat which needs to be absorbed by high quantities <strong>of</strong> cooling<br />

water. <strong>The</strong> sensible valorisation <strong>of</strong> this externality represents a tw<strong>of</strong>old relief to the environment, since<br />

it reduces the need for fossil fuels <strong>of</strong> the by-product's users <strong>and</strong> since there is a decrease <strong>of</strong> the<br />

negative effects <strong>of</strong> re-feeding the warm water to the water source. In addition, it improves the plant's<br />

overall energy efficiency.<br />

In the field <strong>of</strong> renewable energies, operations <strong>of</strong>ten generate heat, but also bio gas <strong>and</strong> fertilizers - as<br />

for example in organic waste plants. For these much smaller plants, the exploitation <strong>of</strong> by-products is<br />

not only environmentally desirable, but <strong>of</strong>ten is decisive for the project's pr<strong>of</strong>itability. In most


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

circumstances, the implementation <strong>of</strong> such efficiency-improving projects depends on the cooperation<br />

<strong>of</strong> local stakeholders.<br />

In the case <strong>of</strong> Axpo's nuclear power plant in Beznau, the firm's political skills, its local embeddedness<br />

<strong>and</strong> empathy to the stakeholder's needs <strong>and</strong> expectations allowed it to build a long-distance heating<br />

network connecting it with the surrounding communities <strong>and</strong> households. Today, this network is<br />

managed by a separate legal entity, REFUNA, which has been able to convince further villages to<br />

join. With view at Axpo's renewable energies unit, local partnerships with organic waste producers<br />

<strong>and</strong> collectors, as well as sewage plants allow it to optimally use synergies with its partners.<br />

Example: Holcim's efficient fuel projects<br />

In the cement industry, cement producers more <strong>and</strong> more begin to valorise the by-products <strong>of</strong> other<br />

industries, through the use <strong>of</strong> alternative fuels or raw materials (AFR) for their cement <strong>and</strong> clinker<br />

production. In these endeavours Holcim is among the pioneers, engaging in so-called co-processing<br />

production with the objective to reduce overall CO2 emissions. Examples for the valorisation <strong>of</strong> other<br />

industries' by-products are biomass from agricultural waste (e.g. rice hulls, sugarcane waste), meat<br />

<strong>and</strong> bone meal, <strong>and</strong> sewage sludge. In some cases Holcim is able to further valorise the heat produced<br />

in its kilns, as demonstrated in two <strong>of</strong> its Swiss plants, which supply some 600 households with<br />

district-heating.<br />

Example: Airports <strong>and</strong> shopping centres<br />

A different kind <strong>of</strong> by-product is very pr<strong>of</strong>itably exploited by airports, which have developed solutions<br />

to benefit from the streams <strong>of</strong> passengers, visitors, employees, <strong>and</strong> other people frequenting their<br />

facilities. Zurich Airport is one <strong>of</strong> the world's most successful airports cum shopping centre, based on<br />

the average spending per passenger, <strong>and</strong> over time has developed into Switzerl<strong>and</strong>'s third biggest mall<br />

in terms <strong>of</strong> revenues. <strong>The</strong> overall cash-flows thus ensure the economic viability <strong>of</strong> future airport<br />

expansions <strong>and</strong> investments in infrastructure upgrading or maintenance.<br />

4.9.5 Summary <strong>of</strong> value creation effects in single-unit operations<br />

Value creation can be understood in a number <strong>of</strong> different ways <strong>and</strong> analysed from<br />

different angles. Within the scope <strong>of</strong> our framework, we refer to value in the sense <strong>of</strong><br />

use value, which we underst<strong>and</strong> from a customer-centred perspective - i.e. the rent<br />

which the firm captures by increasing the perceived value <strong>of</strong> its products, <strong>and</strong> from a<br />

firm-centred perspective - i.e. the value created inside the firm, which is not perceived<br />

by the end-customer. We set our research focus on firms, which are attributed to<br />

utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based industries <strong>of</strong> national strategic importance, in order to<br />

identify the fields within which these firms may create value, under consideration <strong>of</strong><br />

their specific characteristics <strong>and</strong> despite their constraints. <strong>The</strong> insights from empirical<br />

research have led to the conclusion, that value creation seems to predominantly occur<br />

through indirect effects on the firm's relational (social) embedding dimension. In<br />

187


188<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

particular intangible assets, such as the firm's reputation <strong>and</strong> trustworthiness, play into<br />

all <strong>of</strong> the suggested fields <strong>of</strong> value creation, but also the firm’s conscious care for<br />

building <strong>and</strong> maintaining strong stakeholder relationships. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the<br />

structural (economic) dimension <strong>of</strong> firm embedding ultimately adds to the firm's<br />

reputation <strong>and</strong> credibility, serving as pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> the seriousness <strong>of</strong> its efforts towards<br />

'good corporate citizenship' by delivering also tangible (<strong>and</strong> sometimes costly) signals<br />

<strong>and</strong> results. Thus, by embracing good corporate citizenship, the firm taps a key source<br />

<strong>of</strong> competitive advantage, mitigating risks <strong>and</strong> recognising opportunities from longterm<br />

economic, environmental, <strong>and</strong> social trends.<br />

Table 4-13 summarises the identified dimensions <strong>of</strong> value creation <strong>and</strong> the thereto<br />

related value-creating effects.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

(continued next page)<br />

189


190<br />

Table 4-13: Summary <strong>of</strong> value creation dimensions <strong>and</strong> effects in single-unit operations<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Regrettably, due to the multiplexity <strong>of</strong> the framework's constructs, the identified<br />

dimensions <strong>of</strong> value creation are not distinctly delineable in all aspects. Even so, they<br />

are means to structure the field <strong>and</strong> to reveal the direct <strong>and</strong> indirect workings within


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

the framework. Table 4-14 provides an overview on the links between the<br />

characteristics <strong>of</strong> the firm's embedding capabilities <strong>and</strong> the identified fields <strong>of</strong> value<br />

creation.<br />

Table 4-14: Links between UCFs' embedding capabilities <strong>and</strong> value creation<br />

With view at the construct <strong>of</strong> location-fixity, the results <strong>of</strong> our empirical research<br />

suggest that firms' local dependence is not only an inhibiting factor, but equally may<br />

be the root <strong>of</strong> unique advantages. By linking the firm's future direction <strong>and</strong> the welfare<br />

<strong>of</strong> its surrounding stakeholders, location-fixity creates opportunities for the firm to<br />

accumulate enabling assets with these stakeholders. Thus, the firm may facilitate the<br />

exploitation <strong>of</strong> potentials for a unique positioning <strong>and</strong> strengthen the mobility barriers,<br />

inherent in the nature <strong>of</strong> its industry. If the firm is able to tap these opportunities by<br />

means <strong>of</strong> its embedding capabilities, it therefore is able to reduce its institutional<br />

exposure, respectively to convert its institutional exposure into institutional<br />

opportunities. <strong>Location</strong>-fixity's threats to, <strong>and</strong> opportunities for value creation for our<br />

research object are summarised in Table 4-15.<br />

191


192<br />

Dimensions <strong>of</strong><br />

location-fixity<br />

(1) natural resource<br />

dependence<br />

(2) tangible asset<br />

dependence<br />

(3) dependence on<br />

market proximity<br />

(4) ownership<br />

dependence<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Threats & limits to value creation Opportunities for value creation<br />

growth opportunities limited by<br />

constrained resource availability<br />

rent-seeking from resourcecontrolling<br />

stakeholders (e.g. public<br />

stakeholders)<br />

rent-seeking from relevant<br />

stakeholders, appropriating quasirents<br />

necessary to recover sunk<br />

costs<br />

growth opportunities limited by<br />

growth potential <strong>of</strong> the local market<br />

<strong>and</strong> transportation costs<br />

state-involvement leads to<br />

conflicting orientations, such as<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>it vs. guarantee <strong>of</strong> public<br />

service <strong>and</strong> overall utility<br />

Table 4-15: Value creation effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity for the UCF<br />

4.10 Part two – multi-site perspective<br />

exclusivity <strong>of</strong> resource usage as<br />

mobility barrier, ensuring natural<br />

monopoly<br />

subadditive production function,<br />

ensuring natural monopoly<br />

long-term orientation as signal for<br />

commitment <strong>and</strong> credibility<br />

opportunity for trust building <strong>and</strong><br />

embedding <strong>of</strong> firm with local<br />

customers, reinforcing mobility<br />

barrier against potential competitive<br />

entry<br />

state-involvement (e.g. as public<br />

shareholder) as legitimacy-building<br />

factor<br />

insurance against downside-risks,<br />

since state will not allow the firm's<br />

demise<br />

<strong>The</strong> second part <strong>of</strong> our research framework is concerned with value creation between<br />

multiple units <strong>and</strong> sites, as a contextual complement to the local focus <strong>of</strong> the<br />

framework, presented in the first part. Throughout the subsequent sub-chapters, we<br />

will examine the collaboration <strong>and</strong> resource management <strong>of</strong> multiple location-bound<br />

organisational units - among each other, <strong>and</strong> between the unit <strong>and</strong> the corporate parent.<br />

Within this framework we predominantly employ the research lens <strong>of</strong> strategic<br />

management. We thereby concentrate on single-business (i.e. focused) <strong>and</strong> moderately<br />

(i.e. relatedly) diversified multi-site firms, or other forms <strong>of</strong> multi-site collaboration<br />

with a coordinating focal firm, henceforth addressed as MSF.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

UCF - site<br />

-location-fixity<br />

- institutional exposure<br />

UCF - corporate parent<br />

value creation<br />

RQ 6<br />

interaction<br />

RQ 5<br />

UCF - site<br />

-location-fixity<br />

- institutional exposure<br />

local environment local environment<br />

Figure 4-18: Part two <strong>of</strong> the research framework<br />

Within strategy research, the firm's organisation form is <strong>of</strong>ten regarded as central to<br />

strategic outcomes <strong>and</strong> firm-performance (e.g. Datta, 1991; Hill, Hitt, & Hoskisson,<br />

1992; Markides & Williamson, 1996). We deviate from this emphasis within our<br />

research framework, as the firm’s choice <strong>of</strong> organisation plays a subordinate role for<br />

our research questions. Rather, we set the focus on multi-site value creation from the<br />

specific angle <strong>of</strong> location-fixity. We will start our analysis with a brief introduction <strong>of</strong><br />

the literature on corporate parenting, before concentrating on concepts <strong>of</strong> synergy <strong>and</strong><br />

discussing the value creation potentials <strong>of</strong> MSF within utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based<br />

industries.<br />

4.10.1 <strong>The</strong> role <strong>of</strong> the corporate parent<br />

While the business units (BU) <strong>of</strong> a firm compete in particular markets, <strong>of</strong>ten being<br />

directly engaged in production processes, the firm as corporate parent is usually not.<br />

Much rather, “its role is to oversee, support or augment the primary activities” (C.<br />

Bowman & Ambrosini, 2007: 363) <strong>of</strong> its BUs, <strong>and</strong> to facilitate firm-wide value<br />

creation via organic growth or external development. <strong>The</strong>se tasks may be approached<br />

on the attitudinal continuum between a top-down 'the corporate centre knows best' <strong>and</strong><br />

a decentralised 'laissez-faire' maxim. Whichever approach the corporate parent<br />

chooses, synergy realisation within relatedly diversified firms requires management (J.<br />

Martin & Eisenhardt, 2002) <strong>and</strong> the establishment <strong>of</strong> cooperative organisational<br />

arrangements, in order to coordinate the activities <strong>of</strong> otherwise independent BUs (Hill<br />

193


194<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

et al., 1992; Porter, 1985). Campbell <strong>and</strong> Goold (1995) identify four value-creating<br />

types <strong>of</strong> activities <strong>of</strong> the corporate parent, namely<br />

- st<strong>and</strong>-alone influence: impact on the BU's performance <strong>and</strong> strategies, viewed<br />

as a st<strong>and</strong>-alone unit (e.g. by being involved in the setting <strong>and</strong> monitoring <strong>of</strong><br />

performance targets, approving major capital expenditures, <strong>and</strong> selecting <strong>and</strong><br />

replacing the business unit's leadership crew)<br />

- linkage influence: promotion <strong>of</strong> cooperation <strong>and</strong> synergy-seeking between the<br />

units <strong>and</strong> businesses<br />

- central functions <strong>and</strong> services: support <strong>of</strong> the BUs' <strong>and</strong> the overall business<br />

effectiveness<br />

- business development activities: identification <strong>of</strong> business opportunities by<br />

means <strong>of</strong> acquisitions, divestments, changes in the scope <strong>of</strong> business, alliancebuilding<br />

<strong>and</strong> new ventures.<br />

All <strong>of</strong> these activities may contribute to value creation, but they also have an inherent<br />

tendency for value destruction. This threat emanates from the obvious issue <strong>of</strong><br />

corporate overheads, but also from the ill-judged influence from senior managers <strong>and</strong><br />

information filters (Goold, Campbell, & Alex<strong>and</strong>er, 1998). <strong>The</strong> corporate parent<br />

consequently faces two major challenges towards a positive net value contribution:<br />

First, it has to identify <strong>and</strong> focus on those areas, where it realistically can contribute to<br />

value creation <strong>and</strong> to restrain its influence, where no central linking activities are<br />

needed for the realisation <strong>of</strong> synergies between corporate units. Secondly, it has to<br />

overcome several barriers impeding the collaboration with <strong>and</strong> between its multiple<br />

sites, needing to develop distinct organising capabilities. Thus, defining the corporate<br />

parent's role to effectively contribute to overall value creation remains an act <strong>of</strong><br />

balance.<br />

4.10.2 Inter-site collaboration <strong>and</strong> linkage formation<br />

Depending on firm context, apart from interactions between the corporate parent <strong>and</strong><br />

its BUs, also the exchange between the firm's units <strong>and</strong> sites plays a role in value<br />

creation. As opposed to the corporate parent's strategic contribution, inter-unit<br />

activities build unique problem solving capabilities on a more operational level. Thus,<br />

different units establish linkages among themselves to exchange resources <strong>and</strong> transfer<br />

knowledge. Compared to market exchange, such interaction is characterised by<br />

facilitated communication in the exchange process, based on similar shared values <strong>and</strong><br />

common corporate languages (Tsai, 2000). Consequently, organisational units can<br />

access other units' knowledge <strong>and</strong> learn from each other more easily. Hansen <strong>and</strong>


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Nohria (2004) very generally name five areas <strong>of</strong> value creation between multiple sites:<br />

cost savings through best practice transfer; better decision making through advice<br />

obtained from other subsidiaries; increased revenue through the sharing <strong>of</strong> expertise<br />

<strong>and</strong> products among subsidiaries; innovation through the combination <strong>and</strong> crosspollination<br />

<strong>of</strong> ideas; <strong>and</strong> enhanced capacity for collective action involving multiple<br />

sites.<br />

However, notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing their benefits, the creation <strong>of</strong> such linkages between units is<br />

not easy. Research has shown, that linkage formation in general is a path-dependent<br />

process, whereby prior linkages determine the formation <strong>of</strong> future linkages (e.g.<br />

Gulati, 1995; G. Walker, Kogut, & Shan, 1997). Because relation-specific capital, such<br />

as trust <strong>and</strong> tacit underst<strong>and</strong>ing, develops over time, firms tend to stick to their<br />

coordination routines <strong>and</strong> usually are not actively seeking to establish new linkages.<br />

This inertia is moderated by the degree <strong>of</strong> individuals' 'strategic linking capability',<br />

which determines the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the units' resource exchange <strong>and</strong> knowledge<br />

transfer (Tsai & Ghoshal, 1998).<br />

Since the MSF's specific organisation form is <strong>of</strong> limited importance for our research<br />

questions, we will regard the focal firm's dispersed parts as a not further specified<br />

network <strong>of</strong> organisational units, which are located in different environments <strong>and</strong> which<br />

possess a set <strong>of</strong> relational ties which links them together.<br />

4.10.3 Limitations to multi-site firms within UCI<br />

<strong>The</strong> spatial inflexibility <strong>of</strong> the UCF entails a number <strong>of</strong> disadvantages in its value<br />

creation opportunities across multiple sites, if compared with footloose industries.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se constraints relate to three main issues, which will be further elaborated<br />

subsequently.<br />

(1) Limits to overall value chain optimisations<br />

(2) Constraints through (institutional environment specific) regulatory systems<br />

(3) Constraints due to economic nationalism, respectively protective reflexes with<br />

regard to strategic assets <strong>of</strong> importance to the local economy<br />

(1) Limits to overall value chain optimisations. UCFs are significantly constrained in<br />

the optimisation <strong>of</strong> their productive processes across dispersed sites, since they have to<br />

perform most operational activities in situ. <strong>The</strong> extent <strong>of</strong> these limitations becomes<br />

apparent in the cases <strong>of</strong> patient care in hospital services, passenger <strong>and</strong> aircraft ground<br />

services in airport operation, or oil production on drilling rigs. Consequently,<br />

compared to manufacturing industries there are limited possibilities to pool production<br />

195


196<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

processes for individual components or to combine certain parts <strong>of</strong> the value chain in<br />

order to realise economies <strong>of</strong> scale <strong>and</strong> scope. In addition, the sharing <strong>of</strong> physical<br />

production resources across sites is almost impossible, because UCFs' critical tangible<br />

assets are highly immobile, making it impossible or very costly to displace them<br />

geographically.<br />

(2) Constraints through (institutional environment specific) regulatory systems. <strong>The</strong><br />

high regulatory density <strong>of</strong> UCI impedes exploitation <strong>of</strong> synergies across countryborders,<br />

for example, due to differing st<strong>and</strong>ards for special equipment, products, etc.<br />

Although there is a tendency towards global regulatory harmonisation, structural<br />

barriers concerning differences in the statutory <strong>and</strong> regulatory environment persist<br />

(Sudarsanam, 2003), particularly in the less developed areas <strong>of</strong> the world. In some<br />

cases, these obstacles overlap with the argument elaborated in the next passage - the<br />

defence <strong>of</strong> national strategic interests - since “most rules <strong>and</strong> regulations … are created<br />

by governments <strong>and</strong> are <strong>of</strong>ten the outcome <strong>of</strong> local political processes” (Kostova &<br />

Zaheer, 1999: 70). But also different expectations from the public stakeholders<br />

towards a non-local firm may explain regulatory hurdles. In many countries, firms<br />

with a foreign corporate parent are expected to do more than local companies for their<br />

social acceptance, so that the mere compliance with regulatory minimum st<strong>and</strong>ards<br />

does not suffice to build goodwill <strong>and</strong> would provoke regulatory disappreciation.<br />

Example: Expectations toward Flughafen Zürich as operator <strong>of</strong> Bengaluru International Airport<br />

Air traffic in Bengaluru has grown significantly in the first decade <strong>of</strong> the new millennium, with<br />

passenger traffic increasing from slightly above 3m in 2003 to almost 8m in 2009. This momentum<br />

exceeded the most optimistic scenarios for the capacity planning <strong>of</strong> the new Greenfield airport when it<br />

opened in June 2008. While positive on the revenue side <strong>of</strong> the airport operator, it also put stress to<br />

the infrastructure <strong>and</strong> processes from the beginning <strong>of</strong> operation. Although the airport h<strong>and</strong>led the<br />

high traffic volumes according to international best-practice st<strong>and</strong>ards, a fact that was repeatedly<br />

acknowledged by international service quality benchmarks, the Indian authorities expected a different<br />

kind <strong>of</strong> airport. During its first year <strong>of</strong> operation, the authorities, politicians <strong>and</strong> the media regularly<br />

compared the airport with Asia's biggest hubs, such as Singapore, Seoul <strong>and</strong> Bangkok - all multiples<br />

<strong>of</strong> the size <strong>of</strong> the regional airport, <strong>and</strong> stated their frustration with the appearance <strong>of</strong> the airport <strong>and</strong><br />

its processes. In comparison, the resonance on other Indian airport projects, which were under<br />

control <strong>and</strong> responsibility <strong>of</strong> the Indian government or Indian private firms, was much less critical,<br />

despite in some cases obvious inferiority <strong>of</strong> the services levels. One explanation for such judgments<br />

under divergent yardsticks may be that the major involvements <strong>of</strong> an international airport operator<br />

<strong>and</strong> a German shareholder led to unrealistically high expectations. It took the local operator BIAL a<br />

year <strong>of</strong> continuous high service quality <strong>and</strong> the convincing argument <strong>of</strong> winning <strong>of</strong> a number <strong>of</strong><br />

international awards, until the public view was changed <strong>and</strong> until also feedback from public<br />

authorities <strong>and</strong> politicians on the airport became more favourable.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

(3) Constraints due to economic nationalism. Since UCI are very visible <strong>and</strong> under<br />

close scrutiny from the regulator, politics, <strong>and</strong> the public in general, attempts towards<br />

synergy realisation are a sensitive issue with regard to issues <strong>of</strong> security <strong>of</strong> supply <strong>and</strong><br />

national interest. Recently, there is a renewed tendency in industrialised states towards<br />

economic nationalism 80 , manifesting itself in the “role that the national government,<br />

domestic firms, <strong>and</strong> general public is expected to play in curtailing the involvement <strong>of</strong><br />

foreign firms in the domestic economy” (Akhter, Kim, & Hosseini, 2003: 77; see also<br />

Schedler & Bieger, 2002). As a result, firms optimising their operations across borders<br />

might experience in their host countries a willingness to restrict free market<br />

developments, if the st<strong>and</strong>-alone functionality <strong>of</strong> the firm's local unit is at risk 81 .<br />

Empirical evidence is mostly found in cases, where the state takes influence on<br />

planned mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions, recent examples <strong>of</strong> which being illustrated in Table<br />

4-16. However, economic nationalism influences also established foreign firms'<br />

operations, by imposing costs which do not accrue to firms <strong>of</strong> national origin (cf. S.<br />

Zaheer, 1995). Thus, the consequences for foreign firms are restrictions to the<br />

movement <strong>of</strong> labour, goods, <strong>and</strong> capital at best <strong>and</strong> outright expropriation at worst.<br />

80<br />

See also Akhter (2007), who defines economic nationalism as seeking to "safeguard domestic<br />

resources, industries, <strong>and</strong> people from the control <strong>of</strong> foreign firms, who are considered members <strong>of</strong> the<br />

out-group".<br />

81<br />

In a commentary article, 'European Voice' (N.N., 2006) observes: "EU governments celebrate when<br />

companies registered in their countries take over foreign companies - <strong>and</strong> tend to see it as a sign <strong>of</strong> the<br />

economic potency <strong>of</strong> their industries. But they are up in arms when foreign companies try to take over<br />

their national companies. <strong>The</strong>y <strong>of</strong>ten justify their protectionism with the desire to boost 'European<br />

champions', which would prevent the de-industrialisation <strong>of</strong> Europe, they say, <strong>and</strong> would avoid<br />

restructuring <strong>and</strong> lay<strong>of</strong>fs."<br />

197


198<br />

Industry<br />

(country)<br />

Energy<br />

(Spain)<br />

Energy<br />

(France)<br />

Steel<br />

(Luxembourg)<br />

Ports<br />

(USA)<br />

Various<br />

(Canada)<br />

Airports<br />

(Great<br />

Britain)<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Description Year<br />

As an answer to a takeover bid to Endesa (Spain) by E.ON (Germany), the<br />

Spanish government decided to intervene in order to prevent a take-over <strong>and</strong> to<br />

merge Endesa with Gas Natural (Spain) instead, with the objective to create an<br />

Iberian energy champion. Ultimately the (government-loyal) Spanish regulator<br />

allowed the merger due to mounting pressures from the European Commission,<br />

however, tying it to significant constraining conditions. As a consequence<br />

E.ON withdrew its bid in spring 2007.<br />

<strong>The</strong> French government pushed a merger between state-controlled Gaz de<br />

France (GdF) <strong>and</strong> the private utility group Suez, in order pre-empt Enel's<br />

(Italy) take-over attempt for Suez. Due to political resistance in France, Enel<br />

never <strong>of</strong>ficially bid <strong>and</strong> withdrew from its plans. Suez <strong>and</strong> GdF merged 2007.<br />

Mittal Steel (GB, India) initially made a friendly <strong>of</strong>fer to Arcelor, to which<br />

Arcelor responded by rallying the related governments <strong>of</strong> Luxembourg<br />

(owning 5.6% <strong>of</strong> Arcelor), France, <strong>and</strong> Spain against the deal. Consequently,<br />

Mittal Steel changed strategy after being turned down, which led to a lengthy<br />

takeover struggle. Backed by Luxembourg's government <strong>and</strong> swiftly approved<br />

by its regulator, Arcelor produced Severstal (Russia) as a “White Knight” to<br />

prevent a takeover by Mittal Steel. Yet by June 2006 the merger between<br />

Arcelor <strong>and</strong> Mittal Steel finally was agreed upon, being implemented in the<br />

course <strong>of</strong> 2007. Initial political resistance to the bid were based on economic<br />

nationalism: governments feared for their countries' interests, which they saw<br />

endangered through the entrepreneurial business demeanour <strong>of</strong> Mittal Steel,<br />

contrary to Arcelor's tradition <strong>of</strong> serving public interests <strong>and</strong> giving priority to<br />

securing national supplies.<br />

When Dubai Ports World (DPW, an SOE <strong>of</strong> United Arab Emirates) acquired<br />

Britain's Peninsular <strong>and</strong> Oriental Steam Navigation Company (P&O) in March<br />

2006, a controversy started about P&O's management contracts <strong>of</strong> six major<br />

US ports (plus 14 minor ports). Although the sale was approved <strong>and</strong> regulatory<br />

hurdles have been cleared by the Committee on Foreign Investment in the<br />

United States (CFIUS), various US politicians argued that the takeover would<br />

compromise US port security. After an initial voluntary postponement <strong>of</strong><br />

DPW's takeover <strong>of</strong> significant operations it finally decided to resell the venture<br />

to American International Group (AIG), due to the persisting political <strong>and</strong><br />

national resistance to the takeover.<br />

End <strong>of</strong> 2007 the Canadian Government issued 'clarifications' <strong>of</strong> its FDI rules<br />

for SOE under the 'Investment Canada Act'. <strong>The</strong> new rules included an<br />

assessment <strong>of</strong> the acquisition-impact on the location <strong>of</strong> production sites, as<br />

well as R&D facilities, <strong>and</strong> on whether the bidder will ensure “the appropriate<br />

level <strong>of</strong> capital expenditures to maintain the Canadian business in a globally<br />

competitive position” (Government <strong>of</strong> Canada, 2007).<br />

Two years after Ferrovial (Spain) took over the British Airport Authority<br />

(BAA) Britain's regulator ordered its break-up in order to improve service<br />

quality <strong>and</strong> lower costs by creating a competitive environment for the various<br />

airport operations, cf. subsequent separate text-box.<br />

Table 4-16: Examples <strong>of</strong> economic nationalism in national strategic sectors<br />

2006<br />

2006<br />

2006<br />

2006<br />

2007<br />

2007


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Example: BAA's loss <strong>of</strong> legitimacy after its take-over by Ferrovial<br />

In June 2006, Great Britain's BAA accepted a take-over bid by the Spanish infrastructure group<br />

Ferrovial, bringing Britain's strategically most relevant airports under foreign ownership. Despite<br />

desolate customer service <strong>and</strong> deterioration <strong>of</strong> infrastructure over the past 30 years <strong>of</strong> BAA's existence<br />

as a private company, the British regulator became active just in the advanced stages <strong>of</strong> negotiations<br />

with Ferrovial, conveying the impression that the impending change <strong>of</strong> ownership had an influence on<br />

the application <strong>of</strong> stricter st<strong>and</strong>ards. BAA operated seven British airports at the time, among them<br />

Heathrow, Stansted <strong>and</strong> Gatwick - it therefore historically had a quasi-monopolist status in the<br />

London area. However, already during the negotiation phase for Ferrovial's take-over the Office <strong>of</strong><br />

Fair Trading announced a competition inquiry into the ownership <strong>of</strong> Britain's airports, which would<br />

potentially result in the break-up <strong>of</strong> BAA. <strong>The</strong>re followed scrutiny <strong>of</strong> the operator's customer service<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ards at Heathrow <strong>and</strong> a review <strong>of</strong> prices <strong>and</strong> charges. Under the header 'Breaking up BAA', the<br />

Financial Times commented in 2008: “in the months since June 2006 … Heathrow has become hated,<br />

a byword for chaos <strong>and</strong> incompetence” 82 <strong>and</strong> the Telegraph doubles: “BAA is one <strong>of</strong> Britain's most<br />

arrogant, complacent <strong>and</strong> customer-unfriendly businesses. It's a showcase for the disbenefits <strong>of</strong><br />

immunity from competition” 83 . But when Ferrovial took overin 2006, the airport management was<br />

already complacent. <strong>The</strong> perceived grievances were caused by BAA, whose privatisation in 1987<br />

obviously had not resulted in the hoped for improvement <strong>of</strong> airport infrastructure <strong>and</strong> customer<br />

service. Nevertheless, the regulators decided to take consequences only at the time, when BAA was no<br />

more a British company.<br />

Consequently, the various inquiries <strong>of</strong> the national regulatory bodies focused on BAA's lack <strong>of</strong><br />

responsiveness to the needs <strong>of</strong> its customers (i.e. airlines <strong>and</strong> passengers), the impact on investment<br />

<strong>and</strong> customer service, <strong>and</strong> the absence <strong>of</strong> competition - particularly in the London area. Ultimately, in<br />

March 2009 the British Competition Commission imposed on BAA the divestiture <strong>of</strong> three airports,<br />

namely Gatwick, Stansted, <strong>and</strong> one <strong>of</strong> the Scottish airports, based on the findings <strong>of</strong> their inquiry.<br />

While there certainly were valid reasons for the decision, interestingly the concerted regulatory<br />

activity only started when a change in ownership to a foreign firm became imminent. It is st<strong>and</strong>ing to<br />

reason, that the increased scrutiny, inter alia, is linked to the loss <strong>of</strong> BAA's organisational legitimacy:<br />

Ferrovial - as a Spanish company - apparently was not able to overcome its liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness<br />

<strong>and</strong> to become a credible investor <strong>and</strong> airport operator in the British interest. As a consequence the<br />

parent firm faced higher transaction costs during the various disputes, lower revenues due to a<br />

reduced cap on its allowed return on capital, <strong>and</strong> increased cost <strong>of</strong> capital due to the perceived<br />

increased risk to creditors. However, what hurts Ferrovial most is the divestiture <strong>of</strong> three <strong>of</strong> BAA's<br />

most precious assets at a loss, compared to the premium it paid for purchasing them in a bundle.<br />

82<br />

N.N. (2008, April 22). Breaking up BAA. Financial Times. Retrieved January 15, 2010, from<br />

http://www.ft.com.<br />

83<br />

R<strong>and</strong>all, J. (2008, August 20). BAA break-up is needed for better airports. Telegraph. Retrieved<br />

January 15, 2010 from http://www.telegraph.co.uk.<br />

199


200<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

While the second <strong>and</strong> third limitation generally pertain to all multinational<br />

corporations, they are particularly salient to location-bound firms within UCI, which<br />

are not only visible, but also highly sensitive contributors to the functioning <strong>of</strong> the<br />

national economy, <strong>of</strong>ten being symbols <strong>of</strong> national pride <strong>and</strong> progress. As a<br />

consequence, in their search for synergy across their multiple sites, UCF need to be<br />

sensitive to the local environment, as described in the single-site framework. Due to<br />

these specific limitations, <strong>and</strong> regardless <strong>of</strong> their organisational form, their synergy<br />

<strong>and</strong> value creation potentials are mainly to be found in the realm <strong>of</strong> intangibles, as will<br />

be discussed next.<br />

4.10.4 Value creation in the multi-site firm<br />

From a strategic management perspective, the fundamental argument for firms'<br />

expansion - geographically or towards related businesses - has been provided by Edith<br />

Penrose (1959). Viewing the firm as a bundle <strong>of</strong> resources, she argued that the reason<br />

for expansion lies in underutilisation <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> these resources, which induces firms<br />

to search for opportunities to employ these slack resources in other rent-creating<br />

activities. According to this logic, value creation in the operation <strong>of</strong> more than one<br />

firm site or business unit stems from an improved utilisation <strong>of</strong> a firm's existing<br />

resources.<br />

Stated differently, firms are seeking to realise synergies, defined as “the value that is<br />

created <strong>and</strong> captured, over time, by the sum <strong>of</strong> the businesses together relative to what<br />

it would be separately” (J. Martin & Eisenhardt, 2001: 3). While <strong>of</strong>ten narrowed down<br />

to reduction <strong>of</strong> cost 84 (Besanko, Dranove, & Shanley, 2000), this inclusive view on<br />

synergies also considers value creation from revenue increases <strong>and</strong> from a reduced<br />

need for investment. Importantly, it also takes account <strong>of</strong> the temporal nature <strong>of</strong><br />

synergies, incorporating value creation effects <strong>of</strong> sharing <strong>and</strong> recombining resources<br />

over time (J. Martin & Eisenhardt, 2003). Moreover, this notion <strong>of</strong> synergy stresses the<br />

importance <strong>of</strong> the firm's internal <strong>and</strong> external environment, as well as the relationships<br />

between them for the exploitation <strong>of</strong> synergies (J. Martin & Eisenhardt, 2002). Based<br />

on this wide conceptualisation, in the second part <strong>of</strong> our framework we equate synergy<br />

realisation between multiple sites (respectively between the corporate parent <strong>and</strong> its<br />

sites) with value creation.<br />

84 Porter (1985: 328), for example, conceptualises synergies much narrower as the results from<br />

businesses' transfer <strong>of</strong> knowledge, or from the sharing <strong>of</strong> activities with "the potential to reduce cost if<br />

the cost <strong>of</strong> a value activity is driven by economies <strong>of</strong> scale, learning or the pattern <strong>of</strong> capacity<br />

utilisation".


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Synergy classification. <strong>The</strong> concept <strong>of</strong> synergy has been extensively researched<br />

within strategic management from a variety <strong>of</strong> perspectives, <strong>and</strong> resulting in a number<br />

<strong>of</strong> definitions, typologies <strong>and</strong> classifications (e.g. Ans<strong>of</strong>f, 1965; Goold & Campbell,<br />

2000). In a recent contribution to the field, Knoll (2008) integrated existing approaches<br />

to synergy into a consistent overall typology, as illustrated in Table 4-17, on which we<br />

will draw for our framework.<br />

Synergy<br />

Type<br />

(1) operative<br />

synergies<br />

(2) market power<br />

synergies<br />

(3) financial synergies<br />

Definition Sub-Categories<br />

performance<br />

advantages <strong>of</strong> MSF<br />

from leveraging<br />

operative resources<br />

across their sites <strong>and</strong><br />

related businesses<br />

(continued next page)<br />

performance<br />

advantages <strong>of</strong> MSF<br />

from leveraging market<br />

power resources across<br />

sites & related<br />

businesses<br />

performance<br />

advantages <strong>of</strong> MSF<br />

from leveraging<br />

financial resources<br />

across sites <strong>and</strong> related<br />

businesses<br />

- efficiency synergies: cost subadditivities from sharing similar<br />

operative resources across businesses<br />

- growth synergies: valuable revenue superadditivities from<br />

combining complementary operative resources across<br />

businesses<br />

- procurement power: pooling <strong>of</strong> purchasing volumes to<br />

maximise price advantage<br />

- reciprocal buying <strong>and</strong> selling: establishment <strong>of</strong> advantageous<br />

buying <strong>and</strong> selling relationships<br />

- reduced corporate risk: building <strong>of</strong> portfolio with negatively<br />

correlated cash flows to benefit from coinsurance effects<br />

- internal capital market: establishment <strong>of</strong> an internal capital<br />

market to benefit from reduced financing costs <strong>and</strong> increased<br />

financial flexibility<br />

- tax advantages: reduction <strong>of</strong> tax liabilities by using losses in<br />

some businesses to <strong>of</strong>fset pr<strong>of</strong>its in others<br />

- financial economies <strong>of</strong> scale: reducing transaction <strong>and</strong><br />

floatation costs in issuing <strong>of</strong> securities, due to larger scale<br />

201


202<br />

Synergy<br />

Type<br />

(4) corporate<br />

management synergies 85<br />

Definition Sub-Categories<br />

performance<br />

advantages <strong>of</strong> MSF<br />

from leveraging<br />

corporate management<br />

capabilities across sites<br />

<strong>and</strong> related businesses<br />

Table 4-17: Typology <strong>of</strong> synergies for multi-site firms 86<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Sources <strong>of</strong> corporate management synergies:<br />

- entrepreneurial capabilities: stimulation <strong>of</strong> business-level<br />

managers to act entrepreneurially<br />

- organisational design: firm capability to create structure,<br />

culture, <strong>and</strong> control systems that motivate <strong>and</strong> coordinate<br />

employees; to balance exploitation <strong>and</strong> exploration; <strong>and</strong> to<br />

continuously align environment, structure <strong>and</strong> strategy<br />

- superior strategic capabilities: intangible governance skills<br />

for better BU performance, as compared to st<strong>and</strong>-alone<br />

4.10.5 UCF value creation in multi-site operations<br />

Although Knoll's (2008) synergy typology was devised for multi-business firms, we<br />

argue, that the identified categories equally apply for single-business firms <strong>and</strong> related<br />

diversifiers, which exploit international - as opposed to inter-industry variation. <strong>The</strong><br />

emphases <strong>and</strong> significance <strong>of</strong> the identified synergy types are different, though: the<br />

more closely related the firm's businesses, the higher the potential benefits from interunit<br />

collaboration (Hansen & Nohria, 2004). This applies particularly to the group <strong>of</strong><br />

operative synergies, whereas for example risk reduction through negatively correlated<br />

cash flows 87 , or bundling advantages are less important in related, but geographically<br />

diversified diversifications. With view at UCFs with multiple sites, <strong>and</strong> under<br />

consideration <strong>of</strong> their limitations, our empirical research has led us to identify the<br />

following dimensions <strong>of</strong> value creation:<br />

85 Corporate mgmt. synergies have not yet been conceptualised in strategic management literature.<br />

However, research suggests that these synergies exist, capturing the performance increases <strong>of</strong><br />

businesses that directly result from the activities <strong>of</strong> corporate managers. Knoll (2008: 98) specifies "if<br />

a firm possesses valuable corporate management capabilities, chances are high that the synergies<br />

derived from them contribute to corporate advantage because these capabilities are likely to be rare,<br />

causally ambiguous <strong>and</strong> socially complex". To bridge the conceptual gap, <strong>and</strong> building on the claim<br />

that corporate management capabilities may contribute to synergy realisation, we therefore draw on<br />

the identified capabilities as a substitute for the typology for the purpose <strong>of</strong> our research framework.<br />

86 Adapted on the basis <strong>of</strong> Knoll, 2008.<br />

87<br />

Apart from business diversification, also geographical diversification can be a means to spread risks,<br />

depending on the industry <strong>and</strong> firm context.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

(1) Relational dimension. <strong>The</strong> corporate parent's reputation <strong>and</strong> its experience from<br />

operations in different institutional <strong>and</strong> cultural environments form the basis for<br />

value creation in operating across units. <strong>The</strong> MSF's contribution lies in<br />

reputational signalling effects to the local unit's environment, <strong>and</strong> in an<br />

accelerated process <strong>of</strong> legitimisation through heightened institutional sensitivity<br />

<strong>and</strong> empathy.<br />

(2) Resource dimension. By exchanging, recombining, <strong>and</strong> making joint use <strong>of</strong><br />

intangible resources, also spatially inflexible MSF are able to create value<br />

across their units. <strong>The</strong>se contributions are particularly valuable in the areas <strong>of</strong><br />

best practice exchange, <strong>and</strong> the exploitation <strong>of</strong> management synergies <strong>and</strong><br />

financial synergies.<br />

(3) Institutional dimension. In its interactions with public stakeholders, MSF are<br />

able to build trust by enforcing effective compliance monitoring across their<br />

units, making their business activities <strong>and</strong> externalities transparent, <strong>and</strong><br />

demonstrating good corporate citizenship. Through its extensive experience, the<br />

corporate parent is able to effectively support the local unit in regulatory<br />

lobbying. Thus, it contributes to value creation by efficiently mitigating the<br />

risks inherent to firm foreignness, foreseeing the intricate challenges <strong>of</strong> a new<br />

host country environment as a result <strong>of</strong> their extensive institutional experience<br />

from other operations.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se three dimensions <strong>of</strong> value creation in multi-site situations will be further<br />

elaborated subsequently.<br />

4.10.6 Relational dimension <strong>of</strong> multi-site value creation<br />

While a number <strong>of</strong> influential streams within the synergy literature assume a rather<br />

under-socialised <strong>and</strong> simplistic perspective <strong>of</strong> corporate action (e.g. transaction-cost<br />

economics, agency <strong>and</strong> contingency theory) (J. Martin & Eisenhardt, 2003), recent<br />

research changes focus from a static view on synergy towards a more dynamic<br />

perspective, acknowledging that synergy realisation depends on context. Thus, the<br />

need to frequently realign firm resources for the exploitation <strong>of</strong> shifting market<br />

opportunities is better incorporated. In such dynamic environments synergy realisation<br />

to a growing degree relies on intangibles, such as knowledge, br<strong>and</strong>, reputation <strong>and</strong>,<br />

importantly, organisational legitimacy - linking strategic management with<br />

institutional research.<br />

203


204<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

MSF <strong>of</strong>ten operate in differing institutional environments 88 , with their units linked<br />

through shared policies or strategies. As a consequence, their organisational legitimacy<br />

spans multiple levels <strong>and</strong> scales, taking different forms at the individual sites <strong>and</strong> for<br />

the overall firm. Compared to single-site organisations, this bears an additional<br />

element <strong>of</strong> complexity with regard to the dimensions that influence organisational<br />

legitimacy, such as (1) the legitimating environment; (2) the organisation itself; <strong>and</strong><br />

(3) the process <strong>of</strong> legitimisation (Kostova & Zaheer, 1999). Importantly, the<br />

legitimacy <strong>of</strong> the firm's subunits is interdependent with the legitimacy <strong>of</strong> the overall<br />

system. As a result, there are possible 'legitimacy spillovers' - negative <strong>and</strong> positive -<br />

between the different parts <strong>of</strong> the organisation. Such spillovers illustrate the<br />

opportunities <strong>and</strong> simultaneous vulnerability <strong>of</strong> the focal firm with regard to overall<br />

legitimacy: local legitimacy <strong>of</strong> a firm's subunit is not only inferred from its local<br />

activities, but also from the social approval <strong>and</strong> reputation <strong>of</strong> other firm units, as well<br />

as the corporate parent.<br />

Under such a systemic perspective, the multi-site UCF contributes to local value<br />

creation by bringing in its experience with non-familiar institutional environments. On<br />

a relational dimension, it has the opportunity to support the local unit on two <strong>of</strong> the<br />

afore-mentioned legitimisation dimensions, namely<br />

- on the organisational dimension: through affiliation with a corporate parent<br />

respectively a focal firm, the local unit benefits from signalling effects; <strong>and</strong><br />

- on the process dimension: the corporate parent draws from its experience with<br />

other units, thus being highly sensitive towards different institutional <strong>and</strong><br />

cultural environments.<br />

Signalling on the basis <strong>of</strong> reputation <strong>and</strong> identity. Originating from contract theory,<br />

the concept <strong>of</strong> signalling developed from the notion <strong>of</strong> information asymmetry<br />

between economic agents. <strong>The</strong> objective <strong>of</strong> signals is to reduce uncertainty on quality<br />

in markets: economic actors rely on them, when a direct quality evaluation is too<br />

difficult, costly, or dangerous. Thus, signals are designed to communicate, transmitting<br />

information from those who have more <strong>of</strong> it to those who are less informed (Spence,<br />

2002). More formally<br />

a signal is a perceivable action or structure that is intended to or has evolved to<br />

indicate an otherwise imperceivable quality about the signaller or the signaller’s<br />

88 Each <strong>of</strong> these institutional environments has its own set <strong>of</strong> regulatory, cognitive, <strong>and</strong> normative<br />

domains, see also sub-chapter. 4.2.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

environment. <strong>The</strong> purpose <strong>of</strong> a signal is communication <strong>and</strong> its goal is to alter the<br />

receiver’s beliefs or behaviour. (Donath, 2007: 3)<br />

Within strategic management research, signalling is <strong>of</strong>ten researched in relation to<br />

reputation <strong>and</strong> trust (e.g. Fombrun & Shanley, 1990; Nayyar, 1990). Reputations<br />

summarise a good deal <strong>of</strong> information about firms <strong>and</strong> shape the responses <strong>of</strong> the<br />

firm's stakeholders (Teece et al., 1997). This intangible asset thus enables the firm to<br />

achieve various goals in its stakeholder interaction. In our framework, we therefore<br />

draw on the stipulated link between reputation <strong>and</strong> signalling: when the parent's<br />

reputational asset radiates to the local unit's environment, the latter receives<br />

information on the expected future behaviour <strong>of</strong> the firm <strong>and</strong> its local unit. As a<br />

consequence, with their reputation MSF are able to support their local units in<br />

signalling their commitment, conveying trustworthiness <strong>and</strong> credibility.<br />

Thus, with regard to multi-site UCF, the concept <strong>of</strong> signalling describes the use <strong>of</strong> the<br />

corporate parent's reputational attributes for the purpose <strong>of</strong><br />

- facilitating the firm's market entry;<br />

- expediting the local unit's embedding process in institutional environments<br />

where the local unit is not yet firmly embedded: <strong>and</strong><br />

- increasing the credibility <strong>and</strong> status <strong>of</strong> the local unit in order to gain support for<br />

specific local projects, local financing, <strong>and</strong> business development.<br />

Institutional <strong>and</strong> cultural sensitivity. As has been discussed already in the first part<br />

<strong>of</strong> the research framework, the ability to underst<strong>and</strong> a firm's local institutional<br />

environment <strong>and</strong> its stakeholders is a precondition for its long-term success.<br />

Accordingly, based on the firm's empathy for the local conditions, its overall business<br />

culture <strong>and</strong> its organisational logic, the local unit decides on the degree <strong>of</strong> local<br />

adaptation. In its extreme form, adaptation renders the firm 'isomorphic' with the<br />

institutional environment “by adopting organisational forms, structures, policies, <strong>and</strong><br />

practices that are similar to the ones institutionalised in their environment” (Kostova &<br />

Zaheer, 1999: 71). In multi-site firms with operations in widely differing institutional<br />

environments, this option may not be feasible, stretching the organisational cohesion<br />

requirements <strong>and</strong> the local 'way <strong>of</strong> doing things' too far (Westney, 1993). In its less<br />

far-reaching version, firm adaptation happens selectively <strong>and</strong> resembles a negotiation<br />

process towards legitimisation. This approach is particularly valuable in institutional<br />

environments, which are conflicting with the firm's home environment. Firms with<br />

little experience in geographical expansion usually are facing higher transaction costs,<br />

due to their 'liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness' <strong>and</strong> their “alien status [that] always imposes<br />

205


206<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

some penalty on managerial effectiveness” (Caves, 1971: 6). In the case <strong>of</strong> an<br />

experienced MSF, these transaction costs are moderated by the “extensive<br />

organisational experience [<strong>of</strong> the corporate parent] in dealing with legitimacy issues<br />

<strong>and</strong> expertise in scanning different institutional environments, identifying important<br />

legitimating actors, making sense <strong>of</strong> their legitimacy requirements, <strong>and</strong> negotiating<br />

with them” (Kostova & Zaheer, 1999: 71). Depending on the size <strong>of</strong> the corporate<br />

parent <strong>and</strong> the strategic relevance <strong>of</strong> the local unit for the local environment, this<br />

approach may also increase the firm's bargaining power in the interaction with the<br />

public stakeholders. <strong>The</strong> corporate parent's cultural <strong>and</strong> institutional empathy <strong>and</strong><br />

experience thus creates value through<br />

- lower transaction costs <strong>of</strong> the local unit <strong>and</strong> faster time to implementation <strong>of</strong><br />

local projects, due to better sense-making <strong>of</strong> the institutional environment's<br />

legitimacy requirements<br />

- increased managerial effectiveness<br />

- increased bargaining power by the corporate parent's adequate <strong>and</strong> sensitive<br />

interference with local issues<br />

Summary. Both <strong>of</strong> the described fields <strong>of</strong> MSF value contribution, i.e. signalling <strong>and</strong><br />

cultural sensitivity, are highly relevant in the initial legitimisation process <strong>of</strong> the local<br />

unit. However, established local units have to be aware <strong>of</strong> the possibility <strong>of</strong> negative<br />

spill-over effects from other units <strong>and</strong> the corporate parent, which might equally pose a<br />

threat to maintaining local legitimacy (Kostova & Zaheer, 1999). Affiliation with the<br />

corporate parent, again, implies potentials for value creation <strong>and</strong> the risk <strong>of</strong> value<br />

destruction.<br />

4.10.7 Resource dimension <strong>of</strong> multi-site value creation<br />

Sharing resources between various BUs frequently implies the use <strong>of</strong> common<br />

production factors, with the objective to achieve economies <strong>of</strong> scope 89 . <strong>The</strong> potential<br />

to create value therefore is a function <strong>of</strong> both, subadditive costs <strong>and</strong> superadditive<br />

values <strong>of</strong> the underlying resource combinations (Tanriverdi & Venkatraman, 2005). In<br />

the case <strong>of</strong> the multi-site UCF <strong>and</strong> its spatial limitations, cross-unit value creation<br />

predominantly takes place outside the domain <strong>of</strong> physical production. <strong>The</strong> value <strong>of</strong><br />

managing across the firm's units rests not so much on the exploitation <strong>of</strong> differentials<br />

in factor <strong>and</strong> product markets, but on the transfer <strong>of</strong> learning <strong>and</strong> innovations, as well<br />

89 Economies <strong>of</strong> scope are realised where joint production costs are less than the sum <strong>of</strong> st<strong>and</strong> alone<br />

production costs.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

as the enhanced leverage to respond to competitors' <strong>and</strong> governments' threats. Thus, by<br />

the joint use, exchange, <strong>and</strong> recombination <strong>of</strong> intangibles, the firm is able to use them<br />

better as compared to their st<strong>and</strong>-alone use within each <strong>of</strong> its units. Based on our<br />

empirical research <strong>and</strong> with reference to Knoll's (2008) synergy typology, the<br />

following fields <strong>of</strong> resource-based value creation have been identified <strong>and</strong> will be<br />

discussed subsequently:<br />

(1) sharing <strong>of</strong> best practices<br />

(2) drawing on management skills from the corporate parent or the focal firm<br />

(3) exploitation <strong>of</strong> financial synergies<br />

(1) Knowledge resources & best practice synergies. Out <strong>of</strong> all intangibles,<br />

knowledge certainly is the most significant resource for the creation <strong>of</strong> synergies: it is<br />

one <strong>of</strong> the few assets that grow most when shared. Categorised into tacit <strong>and</strong> explicit<br />

knowledge, the first-mentioned is linked to individuals, residing in the minds <strong>of</strong> human<br />

resources. Consequently, it is costly to articulate <strong>and</strong> communicate. Explicit<br />

knowledge, on the other h<strong>and</strong>, is codified, i.e. embedded in product <strong>and</strong> process<br />

technologies, patents, organisational processes, routines, <strong>and</strong> rules, <strong>and</strong> can be<br />

expressed <strong>and</strong> communicated (Tanriverdi & Venkatraman, 2005). Exchanging<br />

knowledge resources in the organisational context pertains to the process by which it<br />

flows through the corporation <strong>and</strong> is recombined into new value-creating synergies (J.<br />

Martin & Eisenhardt, 2002). Thus, by using the same knowledge resources across<br />

multiple businesses, firms are able to create economies <strong>of</strong> scope. Unfortunately, such<br />

knowledge exchange is not trivial: efficiency <strong>and</strong> effectiveness depend on various<br />

factors, such as the characteristics <strong>of</strong> the knowledge sender <strong>and</strong> recipient, the<br />

relationship between them, respectively the organisational context within which the<br />

transfer occurs (cf. Kogut & Z<strong>and</strong>er, 1992; Szulanski, 2003). Most importantly, it<br />

depends on the characteristics <strong>of</strong> organisational knowledge being transferred: the more<br />

codified, the easier a successful transfer can be attained, <strong>and</strong> the weaker is the need for<br />

geographical proximity. Despite the difficulties in sharing knowledge, it has<br />

advantages over the transfer <strong>of</strong> physical assets, “because it can be more readily<br />

transferred <strong>and</strong> applied in very different situations” (J. Martin & Eisenhardt, 2002). If<br />

done effectively <strong>and</strong> efficiently, it signifies the most important competitive dimension<br />

(Kogut & Z<strong>and</strong>er, 1992). <strong>The</strong>reby, the processes that facilitate knowledge transfer <strong>and</strong><br />

recombination represent a particularly important source <strong>of</strong> synergy from (intertemporal)<br />

scope economies (Singh & Montgomery, 1987).<br />

207


208<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

In the intra-organisational context, the transfer <strong>of</strong> knowledge is also known as best<br />

practice exchange, connoting “the firm's replication <strong>of</strong> an internal practice that is<br />

performed in a superior way in some part <strong>of</strong> the organisation <strong>and</strong> is deemed superior to<br />

internal alternate practices <strong>and</strong> known alternatives outside the company” (Szulanski,<br />

1996: 28). It is a dyadic exchange <strong>of</strong> the firm's knowledge between a source <strong>and</strong> a<br />

recipient unit, in which the identity <strong>of</strong> the recipient matters. Winter (1995) even<br />

conceptualises best practice exchange as the replication <strong>of</strong> organisational routines, i.e.<br />

the exact or partial replication <strong>of</strong> a web <strong>of</strong> coordinating relationships which connects<br />

specific resources to the effect that a similar set <strong>of</strong> resources is coordinated by a very<br />

similar web <strong>of</strong> relationships. Since part <strong>of</strong> these practices <strong>and</strong> routines is tacit,<br />

difficulties in such a replication are most likely to emanate from causal ambiguity<br />

about these connections <strong>and</strong> how the relationships interact in the activity or process<br />

(Lippman & Rumelt, 1982; M. Polanyi, 1962).<br />

In their management across multiple sites, UCF thus have a potential to exploit their<br />

cumulated knowledge <strong>and</strong> to create value by exchanging best practices. Particularly<br />

with regard to explicit knowledge, such as process knowledge, codified in st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

operating procedures (SOP), as well as technological best practice, the roll-out across<br />

all parts <strong>of</strong> the organisation can be managed effectively. Due to the subadditivity <strong>of</strong><br />

their production function, small changes in utilities' operation may have a considerable<br />

impact on overall productivity, in parallel potentially also positively impacting safety<br />

<strong>and</strong> reliability. <strong>The</strong>refore, the exchange <strong>of</strong> codified knowledge can already effect<br />

major improvements. Taking the example <strong>of</strong> airport management, a major part <strong>of</strong> the<br />

performance <strong>of</strong> airports derives from adherence to best practice SOPs <strong>and</strong> the right<br />

technological devices, thus allowing for an efficient knowledge transfer. However,<br />

productive knowledge is embodied in ways rendering a simple information transfer<br />

insufficient (Teece et al., 1997): in order to reach operating excellence this explicit<br />

knowledge is inextricably linked with tacit <strong>and</strong> socially constructed knowledge, as for<br />

example the establishment <strong>of</strong> a safety culture or instilment <strong>of</strong> a true service orientation<br />

in the firm's employees. To convey <strong>and</strong> share this fraction <strong>of</strong> best practice is<br />

considerably more challenging: by dispatching human resources from one BU to<br />

another, the reuse <strong>of</strong> tacit knowledge may be facilitated. But this process is slow <strong>and</strong><br />

only a small number <strong>of</strong> units can benefit from the knowledge exchange at any given<br />

time. <strong>The</strong>refore, while the value creation potential is significant, UCF must be aware,<br />

that best practice sharing is an enduring endeavour that requires patience.<br />

Best practice transfer usually takes place through BU interaction. But to achieve proactive<br />

knowledge exchange, the corporate parent or focal firm must send the right


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

signals to their dispersed flock <strong>of</strong> managers. Often, there is a lack in mechanisms for<br />

the efficient knowledge-sharing (Markides & Williamson, 1996). By setting the right<br />

incentives <strong>and</strong> fostering a cooperative culture, the corporate parent might succeed in<br />

knocking down the barriers to inter-unit collaboration. In addition, it must establish<br />

routines <strong>and</strong> platforms to facilitate exchange between the units. Most importantly,<br />

though, the corporate parent needs to sensitise its subsidiaries on necessary adaptation<br />

<strong>of</strong> transferred knowledge to fit with the local context <strong>and</strong> requirements. Again, the<br />

corporate parent's experience <strong>and</strong> sensitivity towards cultural <strong>and</strong> institutional<br />

differences adds to an increased awareness <strong>of</strong> the knowledge giver <strong>and</strong> the knowledge<br />

taker <strong>of</strong> what is needed to deploy the best practice successfully in a new environment.<br />

Example: Holcim Group Support<br />

Holcim Group Support (HGRS), based in Zurich <strong>and</strong> in Holderbank, is a service organisation with the<br />

purpose to create value by supporting Holcim's de-central organisations in operational <strong>and</strong> industry<br />

related fields. It fosters knowledge exchange, best practice dissemination <strong>and</strong> ensures adherence to<br />

Holcim's corporate policies. Through its turntable function between the corporate centre <strong>and</strong> the de-<br />

central units, as well as between the units, it facilitates the overall information flow. In addition,<br />

HGRS plays an important role in business development, providing expertise in new market entries or<br />

green- or brownfield projects. One <strong>of</strong> its focus areas is the implementation <strong>of</strong> the corporate SD<br />

initiative, helping its locally rooted firms to further strengthen their stakeholder relations <strong>and</strong> to<br />

reduce its overall global footprint. Complementary to these roles, HGRS is responsible for the group's<br />

corporate strategy <strong>and</strong> risk management. Its over 800 employees (2009) represent Holcim's know-how<br />

<strong>and</strong> capabilities backbone <strong>and</strong> constitute one <strong>of</strong> the group's biggest intangible assets.<br />

(2) Corporate management synergies. Compared to st<strong>and</strong>-alone businesses, business<br />

units within the MSF “have a learning scale opportunity in the development <strong>and</strong><br />

exploitation <strong>of</strong> managerial knowledge” (Tanriverdi & Venkatraman, 2005: 102). Such<br />

corporate management synergies stem from the following superior capabilities (Knoll,<br />

2008):<br />

I. entrepreneurial capabilities, i.e. corporate management's ability to stimulate<br />

business-level managers to act entrepreneurially<br />

II. capabilities in organisational design, i.e. to create structure, culture, <strong>and</strong> control<br />

systems that motivate <strong>and</strong> coordinate employees; to balance exploitation <strong>and</strong><br />

exploration; <strong>and</strong> to continuously align environment, structure <strong>and</strong> strategy<br />

III. strategic capabilities, in the sense <strong>of</strong> intangible governance skills to manage<br />

BUs to perform better than they would if they were independent companies<br />

All three sources play a significant role for MSFs within utilities <strong>and</strong> concessionbound<br />

industries, as our case-study research has shown.<br />

209


210<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

I. Entrepreneurial capabilities. Due to the cumulative experience <strong>of</strong> the overall firm,<br />

<strong>and</strong> insights into best practices all over the organisation, the corporate parent has the<br />

capacity to see future trends <strong>and</strong> opportunities, complementary to the insights <strong>of</strong> the<br />

local units in their local environments. Depending on the corporate culture,<br />

entrepreneurial ideas <strong>and</strong> business development projects might be encouraged from the<br />

corporate parent, giving the local management the needed support - financially, as well<br />

as in terms <strong>of</strong> business advice.<br />

II. Capabilities in organisational design. Different institutional environments <strong>and</strong><br />

cultural contexts may require different approaches towards organisational design, as<br />

may the local regulatory set-up. Since the corporate parent has insights in the relations<br />

with service partners <strong>and</strong> other public stakeholders in a number <strong>of</strong> business contexts,<br />

its experience is invaluable with regard to designing an organisation adequate within<br />

<strong>and</strong> fitting into new institutional environments.<br />

III. Strategic capabilities. In its property <strong>of</strong> monitoring BUs on a number <strong>of</strong> key<br />

performance indicators, the corporate parent is able to take timely influence on BU's<br />

strategic orientations. Particularly with regard to investment management, the parent<br />

has the opportunity to increase the overall value <strong>of</strong> the firm by setting priorities in<br />

capital allocation.<br />

(3) Financial synergies. As opposed to the other two categories <strong>of</strong> resource-related<br />

synergies, which require an interaction between the BUs, financial synergies can be<br />

achieved with no such exchange. Through the availability <strong>of</strong> an internal capital market,<br />

the MSF is able to achieve lower capital costs as compared to st<strong>and</strong>-alone businesses.<br />

In addition, effects <strong>of</strong> geographical risk diversification, co-insurance, <strong>and</strong> reduced<br />

information asymmetries between the BUs may lower the cost <strong>of</strong> issuing new debt for<br />

the company, making it cheaper to raise additional funds. Such financial economies<br />

allow the firm to lower its risk <strong>of</strong> default (Chatterjee, 1986; Haspeslagh & Jemison,<br />

1991) <strong>and</strong> give it greater ability to finance investments internally by means <strong>of</strong> portfolio<br />

management (Lubatkin, 1983).<br />

While these effects are relevant to any multi-site firm, the benefits to UCF are<br />

particularly marked. Not only are they significantly financially leveraged, due to their<br />

capital-intensive assets, but their product dem<strong>and</strong> in some cases is highly correlated<br />

with the business cycle, as for example in the airport industry (volume <strong>of</strong> passengers<br />

<strong>and</strong> cargo), the port industry (volume <strong>of</strong> cargo), power utilities (industrial dem<strong>and</strong> for<br />

electricity), or the cement industry (reduced construction activity). As a consequence,<br />

the risk <strong>and</strong> potential instability from volatile dem<strong>and</strong>, combined with high cost <strong>of</strong>


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

capital is significant. As our empirical research suggests, managing multiple<br />

(geographically dispersed) assets provides UCF with the following financial synergies:<br />

- reduced corporate risk high importance for several case study objects<br />

- internal capital market<br />

- tax advantages<br />

- financial economies <strong>of</strong> scale<br />

high importance for Axpo <strong>and</strong> Holcim,<br />

which are organised as financial holdings<br />

Geographical <strong>and</strong> related-business diversification therefore help the multi-site UCF to<br />

smoothen its revenue fluctuations <strong>and</strong> provide it with greater flexibility to allocate<br />

capital through the availability <strong>of</strong> internal means.<br />

4.10.8 Institutional dimension <strong>of</strong> multi-site value creation<br />

As elaborated in the first part <strong>of</strong> the research framework, institutions form a critical<br />

element <strong>of</strong> the firm's business environment, <strong>and</strong> the interaction <strong>of</strong> our research object<br />

with institutional stakeholders bears significant institutional exposure. But while<br />

institutions usually are perceived as constraining (in the form <strong>of</strong> business policies),<br />

they equally allow for the accumulation <strong>of</strong> valuable institutional assets, leveraging the<br />

firm's competencies to earn economic rents (C Oliver & Holzinger, 2008).<br />

In order to build <strong>and</strong> benefit from such institutional assets, UCFs put efforts into their<br />

organisational legitimisation, thus lowering risks <strong>and</strong> uncertainty from their local<br />

environment. Importantly, their legitimisation activities aim at establishing positive<br />

relationships with their stakeholders - thus signalling commitment - <strong>and</strong> at building<br />

trust <strong>and</strong> credibility. By seeing such relationships as a process, cognitive distance can<br />

be reduced, while furthering empathy on both sides (Nooteboom, 2004). Thus,<br />

although the parties' interests remain conflictive, the nurturing <strong>of</strong> a constructive<br />

relationship facilitates joint solution-finding.<br />

As a further trust-building dimension in the local firm's interaction with <strong>of</strong>ficial <strong>and</strong><br />

sovereign stakeholders, an affiliation with a corporate parent might prove supportive.<br />

Not only can the parent firm add to credibility through its reputation, its endeavours<br />

towards being a good corporate citizen, <strong>and</strong> its efforts to be transparent, it also has the<br />

capacity to support the local unit in lobbying for its interests.<br />

In the following, we will therefore elaborate the two identified fields <strong>of</strong> corporate<br />

parents’ value creation on the institutional dimension: compliance monitoring <strong>and</strong><br />

political support <strong>and</strong> regulatory lobbying.<br />

211


212<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

Compliance monitoring. Through its firm-internal linkages, the corporate parent is<br />

able to establish governance mechanisms with its multiple sites. <strong>The</strong>se include the<br />

monitoring <strong>of</strong> their performance, their strategic <strong>and</strong> financial decisions, but also their<br />

adherence to local, national, <strong>and</strong> international rules <strong>and</strong> regulations. Its motivation to<br />

exercise some control on the dispersed parts <strong>of</strong> the firm is deeply intrinsic: due to the<br />

risks <strong>of</strong> reputational spillovers (cf. sub-chapter 4.10.6), it aspires to ensure an overall<br />

unified underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> good corporate citizenship <strong>and</strong> the need for organisational<br />

legitimacy, as well as simple regulatory compliance. On one h<strong>and</strong>, this can be fostered<br />

by establishing a strong corporate culture as a medium for governance, creating “a<br />

shared 'focus' <strong>of</strong> purpose, meaning (interpretation), st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>and</strong> values <strong>of</strong> behaviour”<br />

(Nooteboom, 2004: 97). On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the corporate parent achieves effective<br />

internal governance by having supportive organisational arrangements in place which<br />

link structure, incentives, <strong>and</strong> control systems in order to sharpen this shared focus.<br />

Martin & Eisenhardt (2002: 22) specify the advantages <strong>of</strong> internal governance within<br />

multi-site organisations as “the ability <strong>of</strong> managers … to reduce the costs <strong>of</strong> intrafirm<br />

exchanges, relative to the costs <strong>of</strong> conducting similar exchanges in the market”. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

advantages also refer to their ability to track compliance issues within the overall firm<br />

construct: where external institutions, such as the regulator, are at an informational<br />

disadvantage in their monitoring <strong>of</strong> the firm's activities, the corporate parent has the<br />

means to eliminate such information asymmetry. Thus, the corporate parent's credible<br />

efforts to establish transparency in their local unit's operation, creates value by:<br />

- Reducing the risk <strong>of</strong> industrial accidents <strong>and</strong> damages through irresponsible<br />

activities. <strong>The</strong> establishment <strong>of</strong> internal control systems <strong>and</strong> the demonstration <strong>of</strong><br />

management attention lead to a joint interpretation <strong>of</strong> good corporate citizenship<br />

<strong>and</strong> responsible corporate behaviour beyond pure regulatory requirements. In<br />

addition, ensuring corporate minimum st<strong>and</strong>ards beyond the regulatory<br />

requirements avoid negative reputational spillovers, which would damage the<br />

overall firm's reputation.<br />

- Decreasing transaction costs with public stakeholders. <strong>The</strong> increased level <strong>of</strong> trust,<br />

instilled by the corporate parent's involvement, may lead to reduced transaction<br />

costs with the regulator <strong>and</strong> the public administration, since a cooperative<br />

relationship fosters joint solution-finding as opposed to legalistic bureaucracy.<br />

- Formation <strong>of</strong> long-term institutional assets. Firm-incentives for opportunistic<br />

behaviour are eliminated, since the advantages <strong>of</strong> possessing invaluable<br />

institutional assets for the local unit's future development outweigh short-term


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

advantages from breaching trust, which would put those assets at risk.<br />

Concomitantly such trust-based interaction increases the local administration's<br />

goodwill stocks for the firm, leading to effects as described in the sections 4.9.2<br />

Value through strategic options <strong>and</strong> 4.9.3 Value through risk decrease.<br />

<strong>The</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> internal governance for MSFs, <strong>and</strong> their respective awareness <strong>and</strong><br />

derived actions are illustrated by the following best practice example <strong>of</strong> Holcim.<br />

Example: Holcim's internal governance st<strong>and</strong>ards<br />

Due to the diversity <strong>of</strong> Holcim's geographical markets, the extreme variance in their host countries'<br />

cultures <strong>and</strong> legal systems, <strong>and</strong> due to Holcim's social responsibility towards its stakeholders,<br />

corporate governance is not only a legal requirement, but assumes strategic importance. Thus, the<br />

firm's intricate system <strong>of</strong> governance <strong>and</strong> control shields it from financial risks <strong>and</strong> protects its<br />

reputation. In its annual report 2009, Holcim states accordingly: “[corporate governance] is the<br />

precondition for the Group’s credibility <strong>and</strong> good reputation <strong>and</strong> strengthens confidence among<br />

investors, business partners, employees <strong>and</strong> the public at large” (Holcim Ltd, 2010a: 25). <strong>The</strong><br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> good internal governance happens on the one h<strong>and</strong> on an individual level <strong>of</strong><br />

empowerment. Holcim established a broad Code <strong>of</strong> Conduct, binding to all employees, for the<br />

clarification <strong>of</strong> what rights <strong>and</strong> obligations apply in the work environment (ibid.). On the other h<strong>and</strong>,<br />

governance implementation takes place on a control level, whereby the corporate centre's independent<br />

internal audit body actively screens central <strong>and</strong> de-central firm activities on a financial dimension, but<br />

also with regard to compliance with external <strong>and</strong> internal guidelines.<br />

Political support <strong>and</strong> regulatory lobbying according to spatial scale. Generally,<br />

firms operating in densely regulated environments with a high perceived degree <strong>of</strong><br />

dependence on government policy, are acutely aware <strong>of</strong> the importance <strong>of</strong> their<br />

political activities (Hillman & Hitt, 1999). Thus, for UCF paying attention to<br />

governmental affairs is vital on the local <strong>and</strong> the corporate level, in order to guard the<br />

firm's interest against adverse regulatory changes, <strong>and</strong> as a means <strong>of</strong> gaining<br />

competitive advantage. Political activity is concerned with the firm's relationship to<br />

government, in particular its interests <strong>and</strong> activities in legislative <strong>and</strong> regulatory<br />

processes. It includes, among others, environmental scanning, lobbying, political<br />

action committees, coalition building (including trade associations), <strong>and</strong> advocacy<br />

advertising (Shaffer, 1995). While it does not enable the firm to reduce its dependence<br />

on the government, political activity diminishes “uncertainties related to the<br />

dependence, <strong>and</strong> … the likelihood that dependence will have negative effects on the<br />

firm” (Getz, 2001). Overall, the objective <strong>of</strong> the firm's political activity is to arrive at<br />

public policy outcomes favourable to the firm's continued economic survival <strong>and</strong><br />

success (Keim & Baysinger, 1988).<br />

213


214<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

For the effective management <strong>of</strong> the political environment, the firm has four basic<br />

strategies at h<strong>and</strong>, as illustrated in Figure 4-19: proactive, defensive, anticipatory, <strong>and</strong><br />

reactive (C Oliver & Holzinger, 2008). Seeing political activity as an opportunity to<br />

create value, UCFs prefer proactive <strong>and</strong> anticipatory strategies. While the anticipatory<br />

approach induces the firm to establish best practices in pre-emption <strong>of</strong> regulatory<br />

changes to come, the proactive approach builds on the use <strong>of</strong> the firm's political<br />

capital. Defined as the ability to influence government policy (Shaffer & Hillman,<br />

2000), political capital is a specific form <strong>of</strong> reputational capital (Fombrun, 1996), <strong>and</strong><br />

its development resembles the development <strong>of</strong> social capital, which is characterised by<br />

a continued exchange relationship between the parties (Nahapiet & Ghoshal, 1998).<br />

<strong>The</strong>refore, a firm's relational approach on public policy facilitates such continued<br />

exchange, employing a mixture <strong>of</strong> anticipatory <strong>and</strong> proactive strategies. By means <strong>of</strong><br />

such relationship-building, the parties are mutually trusting <strong>and</strong> “more willing to<br />

engage in cooperative exchange, which then increases each party's social capital”<br />

(Hillman & Hitt, 1999: 829).<br />

Compliance<br />

Strategic orientation<br />

Influence<br />

Value perspective<br />

Value maintenance Value creation<br />

Reactive strategy<br />

Examples:<br />

• Developing efficient pollution<br />

control processes to meet st<strong>and</strong>ards<br />

• Rapid realignment <strong>of</strong> structures<br />

Defensive strategy<br />

Examples:<br />

• Lobbying to increase entry barriers<br />

• Active advocacy <strong>of</strong> the status quo<br />

Figure 4-19: Alternative political management strategies 90<br />

Anticipatory strategy<br />

Examples:<br />

• Establishing best practices in<br />

anticipation <strong>of</strong> public policy change<br />

• Hiring government experts<br />

Proactive strategy<br />

Examples:<br />

• Redefining constituents’ norms<br />

• Establishing st<strong>and</strong>ards that redefine<br />

current legislation<br />

<strong>The</strong> dimensions <strong>of</strong> political influence include access to policy-makers, knowledge <strong>of</strong><br />

the public policy arenas in which the firm operates, <strong>and</strong> expertise in crafting effective<br />

strategies (Shaffer & Hillman, 2000). In order to be effective on these dimensions <strong>of</strong><br />

influence, the multi-site firm needs to differentiate between its corporate political<br />

90 C Oliver & Holzinger, 2008: 60.


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

strategy <strong>and</strong> the specific conditions <strong>of</strong> their local units: as institutional environments<br />

vary by country, so do firms' political actions. While the local firm knows the local<br />

political environment best, the corporate parent maintains an overall perspective on<br />

current public policy trends. Consequently, the parent adds value within the overall<br />

firm's public policy by<br />

- devising an overall public policy strategy;<br />

- following a proactive relational approach on a bigger geographical scale, i.e.<br />

national, multi-national (e.g. within the European Union), or global;<br />

- supporting the local unit on the basis <strong>of</strong> its vast experience with political<br />

processes, in the form <strong>of</strong> tactical <strong>and</strong> procedural advice;<br />

- providing the local unit with corporate lobbying materials; <strong>and</strong><br />

- making use <strong>of</strong> its corporate bargaining clout on the local level, in order to<br />

further firm-specific interests.<br />

Thus, by being part <strong>of</strong> an MSF, the local unit is able to pursue its political interests <strong>and</strong><br />

to impact policy making in ways which would not be attainable as a st<strong>and</strong>-alone<br />

operation. By mobilising the resources <strong>of</strong> the corporate parent <strong>and</strong> by tapping<br />

experiences <strong>of</strong> other BUs, it can take influence on policy making processes beyond the<br />

local level, as illustrated by the subsequent examples.<br />

Example: Axpo's lobbyists in Berne<br />

Axpo has a number <strong>of</strong> possibilities to have a voice in important political bodies <strong>and</strong> with respect to<br />

relevant decision makers. As a group, it is the largest power producer in Switzerl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> its channels<br />

<strong>of</strong> influence, among others, range from informal interaction with the country's federal councillors, to<br />

the presence <strong>of</strong> two lobbyists in the federal parliament in Berne, the participation in various industry-<br />

relevant committees, <strong>and</strong> an active relationship management with the regulatory bodies. Thus, it is<br />

able to contribute to shaping the Swiss energy policy, <strong>and</strong> to advocate its particular interests on a<br />

national <strong>and</strong> regional level. While Axpo's local subsidiaries are more aware <strong>of</strong> their immediate<br />

political environment, in whose h<strong>and</strong>ling the holding rarely gets involved, the supra-local <strong>and</strong><br />

national lobbying activities are coordinated by the holding.<br />

Example: Holcim's public policy <strong>and</strong> responsible lobbying<br />

On its corporate website Holcim states: “we are committed to working within the regulatory<br />

framework <strong>of</strong> the countries in which we operate, yet believe in the need for open dialogue on issues<br />

relevant to the manufacturing <strong>of</strong> cement <strong>and</strong> concrete” 91 . Ensuing to this statement, Holcim informs<br />

91 Holcim Ltd (n.d.). Public policy, compliance <strong>and</strong> environmental investments. Retrieved March 15,<br />

2010, from: www.holcim.com/CORP/EN/id/1610652470/mod/7_4_5_0/page/editorial.html.<br />

215


216<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

on its lobbying practices, stating that 69% <strong>of</strong> its group companies were engaged in related activities in<br />

2009.<br />

Generally, Holcim narrowly watches industry developments, whose business impact it assesses before<br />

deciding on the appropriate lobbying strategy. As a member <strong>of</strong> various trade organisations, such as<br />

the European Cement Association (Cembureau), Holcim <strong>of</strong>ten is able to place its matters via those<br />

channels. With the objective to promote its position on climate <strong>and</strong> energy, the group also sponsors<br />

'Global Legislators Organisation <strong>of</strong> a Balanced Environment' (GLOBE), a platform for legislators<br />

from a broad political spectrum to exchange on the development <strong>of</strong> sound environmental legislation.<br />

To ensure responsible lobbying also in the de-central parts <strong>of</strong> its organisation the group has corporate<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ards in place, which it developed with WBCSD or UN Global Compact. Furthermore, many <strong>of</strong><br />

the initiatives it develops are cross-checked with these organisations. <strong>The</strong> corporate website informs<br />

on Holcim's government relations as follows:<br />

2006 2007 2008 2009<br />

No. <strong>of</strong> group companies receiving subsidies 10 12 12 15<br />

Average value <strong>of</strong> subsidies from national<br />

governments<br />

2'600'000 4'110'436 4'736'604 3,056,376<br />

No. <strong>of</strong> group companies giving donations 3 5 9 7<br />

Total value <strong>of</strong> political donations 100'000 415'468 1'018'054 279,491<br />

Table 4-18: Holcim's government relations 91<br />

In view <strong>of</strong> the transparent way in which Holcim discloses its lobbying activities, but also its best<br />

practice approach to politically engaging in industry issues, its lobbying strategy certainly is<br />

proactive. As a group Holcim possesses refined expertise <strong>and</strong> adequate resources to support local<br />

lobbyists in their country organisations.<br />

4.10.9 Summary <strong>of</strong> value creation effects in multi-site operations<br />

Firms within utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based industries realise value in multiple-unit<br />

operations mainly through their intangible assets. <strong>The</strong>y support their business units<br />

with their know-how <strong>and</strong> experience from the corporate parent, or by fostering the<br />

exchange between their business units, thus exploiting best practice synergies <strong>and</strong><br />

economies <strong>of</strong> experience. Such value creation may occur on a resource level,<br />

increasing the efficiency <strong>and</strong> effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the BU's operations, but may also stem<br />

from the behavioural <strong>and</strong> institutional dimension <strong>of</strong> interaction between the units, or<br />

with the corporate parent. Not surprisingly, most <strong>of</strong> these effects have general validity<br />

for all firms operating in multiple institutional environments. Within the scope <strong>of</strong> our<br />

research framework, however, we have aimed at identifying those fields <strong>of</strong> value


<strong>The</strong>ory Building<br />

creation out <strong>of</strong> the overall range <strong>of</strong> possibilities that have particular validity for our<br />

research object under consideration <strong>of</strong> its special nature <strong>and</strong> characteristics. <strong>The</strong><br />

subsequent table summarises the identified value creation dimensions, <strong>and</strong> the value<br />

creating activities <strong>of</strong> the corporate parent <strong>and</strong> its BUs within utilities <strong>and</strong> concessionbased<br />

industries.<br />

217


218<br />

(continued next page)<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory Building


4 <strong>The</strong>ory Building 219<br />

Table 4-19: Overview on dimensions, effects <strong>of</strong> value creation in UCF multi-site operations


220<br />

5 Case Studies<br />

Case Studies<br />

<strong>The</strong> inputs for our exploratory work have been drawn from three case studies,<br />

according to the selection logic as described in chapter three. <strong>The</strong> following chapter<br />

provides an overview on the empirical insights <strong>and</strong> establishes the links to the model<br />

presented in chapter four. <strong>The</strong> cases will follow an identical structure, starting with an<br />

overall introduction to the case study object <strong>and</strong> its industry characteristics, <strong>and</strong><br />

gradually progressing along the dimensions <strong>of</strong> the model, linking empirical facts with<br />

the constructed framework.<br />

For best results with the case studies, a number <strong>of</strong> qualitative methods have been<br />

combined. While semi-structured interviews <strong>and</strong> expert discussions have rendered the<br />

most valuable insights, these have been complemented with information from<br />

company documents, media reports, <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial communication from the firms'<br />

stakeholders. In cases where additional insights or clarification was required, the<br />

interview partners were approached a second time. Contrasting the empirical insights<br />

with the author's own pr<strong>of</strong>essional experience in international airport operations served<br />

as additional validation check. Table 5-1 provides an overview on the information<br />

sources, on which we have been drawing for our case studies.<br />

In accordance with the grounded theory approach, information gathering <strong>and</strong> model<br />

development were an intertwined process, which led to the initial basic constructs <strong>and</strong><br />

construct-linkages, <strong>and</strong> which were further developed, complemented <strong>and</strong> refined<br />

through-out the empirical process until a point <strong>of</strong> saturation was reached. In the<br />

following case descriptions, information evaluation <strong>and</strong> analysis is first performed on a<br />

case-by-case basis. <strong>The</strong>reafter, by means <strong>of</strong> cross-case comparison, the common<br />

presence <strong>of</strong> constructs <strong>and</strong> relationships among them are illustrated towards an overall<br />

assessment <strong>and</strong> generalisation.


Case Studies<br />

Data<br />

Collection<br />

Method<br />

Interviews<br />

Company<br />

documents<br />

Media accounts<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

communication<br />

from firm<br />

stakeholders<br />

Purpose Execution<br />

- gather background information on the<br />

organisation<br />

- explore stipulated construct-links or<br />

alternative explanations<br />

- develop <strong>and</strong> validate propositions<br />

- identify further key informants<br />

- identify further sources <strong>of</strong> information,<br />

such as company documents, etc.<br />

- validate information gathered from<br />

other sources<br />

- substantiate insinuations <strong>and</strong> inferences<br />

from interviews<br />

- gather information <strong>and</strong> impulses for<br />

further question-development in<br />

interviews<br />

- draw materials for supportive 'minicases'<br />

to illustrate the workings <strong>of</strong> the<br />

framework<br />

- obtain third party perspective on<br />

company<br />

- validate information from interviews<br />

<strong>and</strong> check consistency with stakeholder<br />

perceptions<br />

Table 5-1: Sources <strong>of</strong> information for case studies<br />

5.1 Case study - energy utilities<br />

24 interviews (semi-structured for<br />

model development; model<br />

validation) with selected experts<br />

from case-study objects<br />

- Axpo: 6<br />

- Holcim: 5<br />

- Zurich Airport: 13<br />

2 interviews (model validation)<br />

with third party experts<br />

- SOE shareholder: 1<br />

- economic think tank: 1<br />

- print-information from<br />

interview partners<br />

- internet research<br />

- print-media<br />

- internet research<br />

Deregulation <strong>and</strong> privatisation <strong>of</strong> electric utilities was first started in Great Britain. In<br />

1979 the government <strong>of</strong> Margaret Thatcher initiated an extensive programme <strong>of</strong><br />

privatisation across various industries, leading also to the unbundling <strong>of</strong> the electricity<br />

sector in 1990/1991. <strong>The</strong>se developments in turn have provided impetus for utility<br />

privatisation in other parts <strong>of</strong> Europe, aiming at the introduction <strong>of</strong> more competition,<br />

ensuring security <strong>of</strong> supply <strong>and</strong> a move towards green energy (cf. Domanico, 2007).<br />

<strong>The</strong> utilities' response to these technological <strong>and</strong> regulatory changes was<br />

221


222<br />

Case Studies<br />

consolidation: with the aim to capture synergies in procurement, production,<br />

marketing, <strong>and</strong> administration they bought other utilities, pursued horizontal <strong>and</strong><br />

vertical integration, <strong>and</strong> exp<strong>and</strong>ed geographically. This process was additionally<br />

supported by politics, which favoured the creation <strong>of</strong> national champions (Domanico,<br />

2007). However, overall acquirers have found it difficult to derive value from merged<br />

utilities, due to acquisition premiums, harsh regulatory requirements, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

overestimation <strong>of</strong> synergy potentials - respectively failure to exploit them (Becker-<br />

Blease, Goldberg, & Kaen, 2008; Morsches, Gell, Finger, Seshadri, & Peters, 2008).<br />

5.1.1 Industry characteristics<br />

<strong>The</strong> electricity sector belongs to the category <strong>of</strong> network utilities, which involve a<br />

natural monopoly network essential for the delivery <strong>of</strong> network services to consumers.<br />

Typical characteristics are large sunk investments <strong>and</strong> the provision <strong>of</strong> essential<br />

services which contribute directly to the private sector output. Since these services<br />

affect the majority <strong>of</strong> the voting population, the latter therefore is concerned to protect<br />

itself against the unregulated exercise <strong>of</strong> market power that a natural monopoly makes<br />

possible. Thus, the electricity sector is one <strong>of</strong> the most densely regulated sectors <strong>of</strong> all.<br />

With regard to value creation in multi-unit operations, power utilities have limited<br />

opportunities for cross-site economies <strong>of</strong> scale in the costly sections <strong>of</strong> their<br />

production process, if compared to other industries. While optimisations may be<br />

achieved within the operational scale <strong>of</strong> single plants, they are not so obvious across<br />

multiple operations. An empirical study on value-creation in power utilities (Bausch &<br />

Raffeiner, 2003) points to the danger <strong>of</strong> negative economies <strong>of</strong> scale through costs <strong>of</strong><br />

complexity <strong>and</strong> high transaction costs. In addition, the regulatory environment <strong>and</strong><br />

political parameters <strong>of</strong>ten impede savings potentials in support activities <strong>of</strong> the value<br />

chain.<br />

5.1.2 Swiss energy market<br />

<strong>The</strong> Swiss energy market is composed <strong>of</strong> a total <strong>of</strong> approximately 1'100 utilities. Many<br />

<strong>of</strong> them have an ownership mix <strong>of</strong> private <strong>and</strong> public investors, the latter being mostly<br />

local municipalities. Electricity supply on the other h<strong>and</strong> is provided by the regional<br />

transmission companies. Despite the high number <strong>of</strong> small utilities (particularly for the<br />

electricity supply to end consumers), also in Switzerl<strong>and</strong> the energy industry has<br />

undergone a process <strong>of</strong> consolidation. With regard to electricity generation the Swiss<br />

market is dominated by four major players with a combined market share <strong>of</strong> 89%. As


Case Studies<br />

the biggest national player, Axpo covers a third <strong>of</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong>'s energy production (cf.<br />

Figure 5-1).<br />

Swisspower<br />

16%<br />

BKW<br />

14%<br />

others<br />

11%<br />

Alpiq<br />

25%<br />

Axpo<br />

34%<br />

Figure 5-1: Market shares in Switzerl<strong>and</strong>'s electricity supply (2008/2009) 92<br />

<strong>The</strong> Swiss electricity generation mix is dominated by hydro <strong>and</strong> nuclear sources (cf.<br />

Figure 5-2), which makes power production one <strong>of</strong> the cheapest all over Europe. <strong>The</strong><br />

low price level is additionally fostered by the fact that all major nuclear assets are<br />

approaching obsolescence, i.e. they are written <strong>of</strong>f. With a look at the future, however,<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> could face supply shortfalls already in a few years time 93 , if it is not able<br />

to replace those assets by new nuclear reactors.<br />

Nuclear<br />

39%<br />

<strong>The</strong>rmal<br />

5%<br />

Figure 5-2: Swiss electricity generation mix 94<br />

92 Axpo Holding AG, 2010a.<br />

Hydro<br />

56%<br />

93 See Axpo's study on electricity perspectives as <strong>of</strong> 2020 (Gubser, Zepf, Hubler, & Jochum, 2006).<br />

94 Bundesamt für Energie, 2010. Electricity from renewable sources is included in the 'thermal'<br />

category.<br />

223


224<br />

Case Studies<br />

On the regulatory side since January 1 st 2009 also the Swiss electricity market is<br />

partially liberalised (lagging one decade behind market liberalisation in the European<br />

Union). With that first stage <strong>of</strong> market opening, power consumers with a dem<strong>and</strong><br />

above 100'000 KWh are free to choose their power supplier. Concomitantly the market<br />

is in the process <strong>of</strong> prescribed unbundling, separating power plants <strong>and</strong> power grids.<br />

As a result,the management <strong>of</strong> the high voltage grid, currently owned by various<br />

power producers, has been transferred to the newly founded 'SwissGrid', a limited<br />

company owned by the major Swiss power utilities. It is responsible for the grid's safe<br />

<strong>and</strong> reliable operation, as well as for grid coordination <strong>and</strong> usage as per terms <strong>of</strong> the<br />

European Energy Exchange (EEX). In 2013, SwissGrid will become owner <strong>of</strong> the high<br />

voltage grid, <strong>and</strong> assumes responsibility for its maintenance <strong>and</strong> extension. Another<br />

novelty <strong>of</strong> the first liberalisation stage is the electricity regulator's (ElCom) overseeing<br />

<strong>of</strong> network tariffs <strong>and</strong> electricity prices. Finally, the last stage towards full market<br />

liberalisation is planned for 2014, when freedom <strong>of</strong> choice will also be introduced in<br />

the market for end consumers.<br />

5.1.3 <strong>The</strong> case <strong>of</strong> Axpo<br />

Axpo is Switzerl<strong>and</strong>'s leading energy utility. It acts as a single-source provider <strong>of</strong><br />

electricity generation, transmission, trading <strong>and</strong> sales, <strong>and</strong> electricity-related services.<br />

While its energy generation is currently focused on Swiss territory, its trading<br />

activities are spread throughout Europe. Within Switzerl<strong>and</strong> Axpo supplies three<br />

million people with energy, as well as around 100'000 businesses.<br />

History <strong>and</strong> organisation. Axpo came into existence in 2001 as a holding, subsuming<br />

a range <strong>of</strong> traditional Swiss utilities, which it kept under their original br<strong>and</strong>s. In 2009,<br />

it has undertaken a rebr<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> its biggest subsidiary 'Nordostschweizerische<br />

Kraftwerke AG' (NOK), with the aim to strengthen Axpo's competitive position <strong>and</strong> its<br />

br<strong>and</strong>. As illustrated in Figure 5-3, the Axpo Group is headed by Axpo Holding AG<br />

<strong>and</strong> comprises the subsidiaries Axpo AG (formerly NOK), 'Centralschweizerische<br />

Kraftwerke AG' (CKW), <strong>and</strong> 'Elektrizitäts-Gesellschaft Laufenburg AG' (EGL) - its<br />

trading arm.


Case Studies<br />

Axpo Holding AG<br />

Central-<br />

Elektrizitäts-<br />

Axpo AG schweizerische<br />

Gesellschaft Axpo Informatik AG<br />

KraftwerkeAG Laufenburg AG<br />

Figure 5-3: Axpo's organisational structure<br />

As a state-owned enterprise (SOE), the Axpo group is wholly owned by the cantons <strong>of</strong><br />

north-eastern Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (Zurich, Aargau, Appenzell Innerrhoden, Appenzell<br />

Ausserrhoden, St. Gallen, Thurgau, Schaffhausen, Glarus, Zug), respectively their<br />

electricity utilities. <strong>The</strong>ir objective, in their capacity as firm owners, is to ensure a<br />

secure <strong>and</strong> inexpensive supply <strong>of</strong> electricity for industrial <strong>and</strong> commercial enterprises<br />

<strong>and</strong> private households within their sovereign reach.<br />

In the subsequent passages, Axpo Holding AG as a group will simply be referred to as<br />

Axpo. Furthermore, in the illustrative examples <strong>and</strong> observations we will only refer to<br />

the precise organisational parts <strong>of</strong> the group, where it adds to clarity. Generally, the<br />

majority <strong>of</strong> the embedded cases refer to Axpo AG, which comprises most <strong>of</strong> Axpo's<br />

power plants, including the new energies division.<br />

Strategic orientation <strong>and</strong> geographical presence. Axpo combines strong local roots<br />

with an international outlook. <strong>The</strong> cornerstones <strong>of</strong> its strategy are:<br />

- to exp<strong>and</strong> its position as an energy supply company in Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

- to ensure reliability <strong>of</strong> supply with its own production capacities<br />

- to exp<strong>and</strong> its trading activities in order to improve links to other countries <strong>and</strong><br />

to exploit opportunities on the European market<br />

Its supply <strong>and</strong> delivery territories in Switzerl<strong>and</strong> span - in accordance with its<br />

ownership structure - the north-eastern cantons <strong>of</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong>. In these regions, Axpo<br />

operates 51 hydropower stations 95 , 3 nuclear power stations, 1 gas power station, <strong>and</strong><br />

63 small-scale power stations with renewable energies 96 .<br />

95<br />

<strong>The</strong> number <strong>of</strong> hydropower plants is higher, because a hydropower station may subsume more than<br />

one plant.<br />

96<br />

Re-enforced by Switzerl<strong>and</strong>'s energy policy agenda, which incentivises energy production from<br />

renewable energies <strong>and</strong> hydro power with a cost-covering feed-in compensation (KEV), the field <strong>of</strong><br />

renewable energies is one <strong>of</strong> Axpo's strategic areas <strong>of</strong> growth.<br />

225


226<br />

Case Studies<br />

On a European scale, Axpo is mainly present through EGL, its trading arm. With the<br />

objective to strengthen EGL's position as a pan-European energy trader, it invests in<br />

the expansion <strong>of</strong> its trading <strong>and</strong> gas business, but also in conventional energy<br />

production capacities <strong>and</strong> renewable power projects (a number <strong>of</strong> projects in Italy <strong>and</strong><br />

Northern Europe are in the pipeline).<br />

Figure 5-4: Axpo's presence in Europe (2009) 97<br />

Corporate philosophy. In spite <strong>of</strong> being state-owned, Axpo clearly is a pr<strong>of</strong>it-oriented<br />

company which positions itself in international markets <strong>and</strong> sets its benchmarks with<br />

privately held competitors. <strong>The</strong> opportunity-driven spirit <strong>of</strong> Axpo is reflected in its<br />

corporate mission 98 , which stresses value creation (“we want to be constantly<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>itable <strong>and</strong> create added value for our shareholders. In this way we can ensure that<br />

we have the freedom to act <strong>and</strong> that we will remain competitive") <strong>and</strong> entrepreneurial<br />

attitudes ("we identify <strong>and</strong> exploit new opportunities at an early stage”).<br />

5.1.4 Axpo's location-fixity<br />

As a power utility, location-fixity is a central factor for Axpo, impacting its<br />

opportunities for value creation <strong>and</strong> available paths for expansion. Table 5-2 provides<br />

97<br />

Axpo Holding AG, 2010a.<br />

98<br />

Axpo mission statement. Retrieved June 12, 2010, from Axpo corporate website:<br />

www.axpo.ch/axpo/en/neue_energien_multi/konzern/auf_einen_blick/leitbild.html.


Case Studies<br />

an overview on the characteristics <strong>of</strong> location dependence <strong>and</strong> how they are relevant to<br />

the company.<br />

Characteristic Applicable<br />

for Axpo<br />

Upstream<br />

Natural<br />

Resource<br />

Dependence<br />

Upstream<br />

Tangible<br />

Asset<br />

Dependence<br />

Downstream<br />

Dependence<br />

on Market<br />

Proximity<br />

Ownership<br />

Dependence<br />

on Owners'<br />

Utility<br />

Function<br />

Comment<br />

� fully applicable / ~ weakly applicable<br />

� With the objective to further increase the share <strong>of</strong> hydropower in its<br />

electricity mix, Axpo depends on the availability <strong>of</strong> locations,<br />

subject to water concessions, that hold water quantities <strong>and</strong> water<br />

streams suitable for power generation.<br />

227<br />

Equally, for its nuclear power generation, it depends on the provision<br />

<strong>of</strong> locations that qualify topographically, for which authorities would<br />

grant a concession, <strong>and</strong> for which it would gain the approval from<br />

local stakeholders.<br />

� Axpo's production sites - be it for nuclear power, hydropower, but<br />

also partly for smaller scale renewable energy projects - are always<br />

associated with major site-specific investments. <strong>The</strong> amortisation<br />

period for an asset ranges from 60 to 80 years, while its overall<br />

lifespan may be significantly longer. Concession periods either<br />

match amortisation periods or are shorter.<br />

~ In theory, power does not depend on customer-proximity. Once<br />

transmission networks are installed, its transportation over long<br />

distance is cheap at minimal power loss. However, limiting factors<br />

are the capacity <strong>of</strong> the high voltage grid, network usage fees, as well<br />

as issues <strong>of</strong> politics <strong>and</strong> organisational legitimacy.<br />

� <strong>The</strong> agenda <strong>of</strong> Axpo's public owners clearly prioritises security <strong>of</strong><br />

supply in their region. However, the ownership strategy leaves Axpo<br />

the freedom to selectively venture abroad.<br />

Nevertheless, the political dimension sets limits to degree <strong>and</strong> type<br />

<strong>of</strong> geographical expansion: Axpo is critically monitored in Swiss<br />

politics <strong>and</strong> by interest groups, because <strong>of</strong> its focus on 'clean'<br />

electricity in Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, while investing in relatively more CO2producing<br />

plants abroad.<br />

Table 5-2: <strong>Location</strong> dependence <strong>of</strong> Axpo by construct characteristics<br />

<strong>The</strong>se ties to its core territories are the foundation to its institutional exposure, as<br />

discussed in the subsequent section. At the same time they represent a fundamental<br />

strength in sight <strong>of</strong> the upcoming liberalisation, protecting the firm as incumbent<br />

through a number <strong>of</strong> mobility barriers.


228<br />

Case Studies<br />

5.1.5 Axpo's environment - institutional exposure<br />

Power utilities always are closely interlinked with national or regional economic<br />

interests. Concerns regarding security <strong>of</strong> supply, as well as electricity price-levels keep<br />

politicians <strong>and</strong> economic interest groups alert on all utility-related issues. On the other<br />

h<strong>and</strong>, due to their externalities, such as CO2 emissions or the production <strong>of</strong> nuclear<br />

waste, power utilities are under the monitoring <strong>of</strong> interest groups <strong>of</strong> all sorts.<br />

Such exposure is felt by Axpo in most <strong>of</strong> its strategic moves, particularly at present,<br />

due to the upcoming replacement <strong>of</strong> its nuclear plant in Beznau. But also on a much<br />

smaller scale, any kind <strong>of</strong> business development project relies on the stakeholders'<br />

'licence to operate'. As the head <strong>of</strong> Axpo AG's business development puts it: “the<br />

external social legitimisation is extremely important - without the approval <strong>of</strong> the local<br />

environment Axpo cannot function” (interview N°2: 2). <strong>The</strong> major dependencies stem<br />

from the local community (society), politics <strong>and</strong> the public administration, respectively<br />

the regulator. Furthermore, Axpo to some extent feels the conflicts <strong>of</strong> interest resulting<br />

from its ownership structure (see below). From a supply-perspective, apart from being<br />

reliant on concessions <strong>and</strong> water exploitation rights, there is also a dependence on<br />

local suppliers in Axpo's renewable energy projects. In wood-fired power plants, for<br />

example, it is the company's credo to source locally, which in turn increases its<br />

exposure towards a h<strong>and</strong>ful <strong>of</strong> suppliers.<br />

In the following we will briefly outline Axpo's stakeholder groups, <strong>and</strong> its respective<br />

institutional exposure towards them.<br />

<strong>Local</strong> community: exposure towards voting population; plant neighbours. <strong>The</strong><br />

local community plays a crucial role in Axpo's planned projects <strong>and</strong> running<br />

operations. Within the Swiss context, owing to the people's strong sense <strong>of</strong> democracy,<br />

major projects may be prevented by a group <strong>of</strong> individuals. In a recent project, where<br />

Axpo planned to install a wood-fired power plant in Würenlingen (Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, canton<br />

Aargau) (cf. interview N°1: 13), the local community pre-empted the realisation,<br />

predominantly due to opposition from the site's neighbours. Although Axpo informed<br />

<strong>and</strong> discussed with most local stakeholders from the very beginning, <strong>and</strong> although its<br />

project hearing with the local community was successful, the change <strong>of</strong> opinion<br />

happened at a point in time, when Axpo thought that all major obstacles were passed.<br />

Civilian interest groups: exposure towards nature conservation <strong>and</strong> fishery<br />

associations. To be successful in the medium-term, Axpo's operations require the<br />

involvement <strong>of</strong> interest groups in order to maintain its operational legitimacy. <strong>The</strong>


Case Studies<br />

following two examples illustrate the importance <strong>of</strong> these interest groups for<br />

successful business development.<br />

(1) Exemplary interest-group involvement in Linth-Limmern. In the major hydropower<br />

project in Linth-Limmern, Axpo's local subsidiary involved the local fisheries<br />

association, as well as the WWF from the very beginning in its project planning. In<br />

this process the parties constructively discussed Axpo's plans to include an<br />

ecologically controversial pump-storage <strong>and</strong> other functions, which have impacts on<br />

the local eco-system. By demonstrating a willingness to make concessions, at<br />

significant cost <strong>and</strong> with reductions to the project's overall capacity, Axpo facilitated<br />

the negotiation progress <strong>and</strong> allowed it to gain the trust <strong>and</strong> approval <strong>of</strong> the relevant<br />

interest groups. A manager at Pro Natura, an influential Swiss environmental<br />

association, subsumes: “those who have understood, that the interests <strong>of</strong> nature <strong>and</strong><br />

l<strong>and</strong>scape have to be considered from the very beginning, will proceed in their<br />

projects” (G. Weiss, 2009). As a consequence, the administrative process progressed<br />

smoothly through all instances <strong>and</strong> construction activities were kicked <strong>of</strong>f as planned.<br />

(2) Interest groups impeding project progress. In less exemplary cases, however, the<br />

consequences <strong>of</strong> weak relations to interest groups can be quite far-reaching. In a<br />

complex hydropower project by Kraftwerke Oberhasli AG (KWO) 99 environmental<br />

interest groups pre-empted the project's realisation for almost 10 years. In 1999 KWO<br />

has launched an investment project for the upgrading <strong>of</strong> its assets in Oberhasli, in the<br />

mountainous <strong>and</strong> ecologically sensitive Grimsel region. Despite its lobbying efforts<br />

<strong>and</strong> endeavours to establish a constructive dialogue with interest groups, KWO was<br />

not able to convince them <strong>of</strong> the ecological balance <strong>of</strong> the project. During this period<br />

<strong>of</strong> legal disputes, KWO's CEO commented: “<strong>The</strong> environmental associations are<br />

capable <strong>of</strong> opposition, but they don't have experience in finding compromises. <strong>The</strong>y<br />

are simply not able to cooperate.” And “the environmental associations are against the<br />

flooding <strong>of</strong> further areas in principle <strong>and</strong> against investments in major technical<br />

infrastructure” (Wartenweiler, 2005). Only in the course <strong>of</strong> 2009 the negotiations<br />

progressed in connection with a partial re-licensing <strong>of</strong> existing installations.<br />

Ultimately, in June 2010, KWO could reach an agreement with its interest groups for<br />

two <strong>of</strong> three partial projects, after the firm consented to a number <strong>of</strong> significant<br />

environmental measures. With this milestone KWO finally had cleared the way for<br />

seeking regulatory approval.<br />

99 KWO are owned by the Bernische Kraftwerke AG (BKW) (50%), <strong>and</strong> the municipal utilities <strong>of</strong><br />

Berne, Zurich, <strong>and</strong> Basel.<br />

229


230<br />

Case Studies<br />

Customers: exposure to powerful local purchasers. Particularly with regard to the<br />

valorisation <strong>of</strong> by-products, Axpo is reliant on the cooperativeness <strong>of</strong> the local<br />

customers - as for example in its exploitation <strong>of</strong> heat externalities. Other than that<br />

there is little institutional exposure from the side <strong>of</strong> customers.<br />

Suppliers: exposure to local feeders for power plant operation; local suppliers for<br />

plant construction; suppliers <strong>of</strong> plant maintenance services. Depending on the type<br />

<strong>of</strong> power production, some plants need a stable external supply <strong>of</strong> fuel for an<br />

uninterrupted operation. Thus, energy utilities are in danger <strong>of</strong> becoming reliant on a<br />

small number <strong>of</strong> local contractors, which guarantee such supply in the long-term.<br />

Particularly the renewable energy plants require continuous replenishment <strong>of</strong> the<br />

respective fuels, thus creating an exposure towards private or public suppliers.<br />

Furthermore, in the project-approval phase, electric utilities may become exposed to<br />

pressures for local sourcing. In order to obtain local goodwill <strong>and</strong> approval <strong>of</strong> a<br />

project, <strong>and</strong> to speed up decision processes, a number <strong>of</strong> services preferably should be<br />

purchased locally. Examples are the commissioning <strong>of</strong> the local engineer, engaging the<br />

local transport <strong>and</strong> hauling company, or working with the local construction firms etc.<br />

Service partners: no significant exposures. Axpo's service partners are mainly the<br />

distribution utilities to end consumers, downstream in the supply chain. Since<br />

interfaces <strong>and</strong> pricing issues are regulated, there are no major issues <strong>of</strong> exposure.<br />

Employees: external job market exposure. Due to Axpo's good labour relations,<br />

there are no internal issues <strong>of</strong> exposure. However, in the external job market the firm<br />

might soon face an exposure because <strong>of</strong> the limited availability <strong>of</strong> qualified engineers<br />

for the planning <strong>and</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong> its upcoming nuclear power plant renewals.<br />

Since a significant number <strong>of</strong> nuclear power plants reach the end <strong>of</strong> their lifetime all<br />

over Europe, <strong>and</strong> since Europe has 'unlearned' its capabilities to build such plants in<br />

the past three decades, a 'war on talent' may be expected (cf. interview N°3: 4).<br />

Public shareholder: public choice conflicts <strong>and</strong> exposure to public administration.<br />

In their dual roles as guarantors <strong>of</strong> electricity supply for the local economy, <strong>and</strong> as<br />

owners <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it-oriented Axpo, conflicts <strong>of</strong> interest may arise from the side <strong>of</strong> the<br />

public administration. In reality, these potential conflicts have no significant<br />

consequences, as Axpo fulfils its sovereign mission according to its stakeholders'<br />

expectations <strong>and</strong> thus enjoys some degree <strong>of</strong> entrepreneurial freedom. In other words,<br />

such conflicts <strong>of</strong> interests play a minor role in the current firm - stakeholder<br />

relationship.


Case Studies<br />

Government, regulator, politics: exposure due to discretion <strong>and</strong> opportunism.<br />

Many utilities' projects are exposed to various forms <strong>of</strong> administrative discretion, due<br />

to the complex approval processes, which are necessary for most <strong>of</strong> them, the<br />

industry's dense regulation, as well as the political dimension <strong>of</strong> utility-related<br />

decisions. Discretion, for example, may be practised on a time-dimension: the local<br />

decision makers may influence the speed with which a project passes through the<br />

administrative process. Axpo has experienced cases, where it has been at disadvantage<br />

as a non-local bidder, as the application processes were purposely slowed down in<br />

order to allow the local competitor to prepare a counter-bid (cf. interviews N°3: 18;<br />

N°1: 15).<br />

Moreover, Axpo repeatedly faced hold-up situations in negotiations to valorise its heat<br />

externalities. <strong>The</strong> firm established a number <strong>of</strong> long-distance heating systems through<br />

which it makes productive use <strong>of</strong> a by-product, thus reaching a better energy utilisation<br />

ratio. Since local administrations know that such measures for improved energy<br />

utilisation are necessary to obtain regulatory approval, they successfully negotiate the<br />

heat pricing to levels well below the benchmark price <strong>of</strong> domestic fuel oil.<br />

In another example <strong>of</strong> political hold-up, Axpo intended to build a larger scale organic<br />

waste plant, spanning the cantons <strong>of</strong> Uri <strong>and</strong> Schwyz. However, since the<br />

administration in Uri did not allow its organic waste to be commercialised outside its<br />

regional borders, the firm was forced to build two smaller-scale plants with adverse<br />

impacts on economies <strong>of</strong> scale <strong>and</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>itability.<br />

With another reference to Axpo's project for a wood-fired plant in Würenlingen, the<br />

firm experienced unfavourable discretion in the interpretation <strong>of</strong> law <strong>and</strong> regulation. In<br />

its preparations for the project approval process, Axpo decided to pre-submit all<br />

relevant information to the local administration, in order to find out if there are any<br />

further issues to be considered. Consequently, it received positive feedback to go<br />

ahead with the <strong>of</strong>ficial submission <strong>and</strong> thus expected a smooth approval process. In<br />

particular, Axpo was informed that no adaptation <strong>of</strong> the cantonal structure plan was<br />

needed. However, as the opinion <strong>of</strong> the local community changed against the project,<br />

the cantonal administration decided that such an adaptation was imperative, halting<br />

project progress for an expected 18 months. As a consequence Axpo suspended the<br />

project for an unknown period <strong>of</strong> time.<br />

Last but not least, there is a political exposure - either directly or indirectly - through<br />

effects on the regulatory dimension. In Axpo's interaction with the regulatory bodies,<br />

national issues are being taken up on the holding level, whereas local or value-chain-<br />

231


232<br />

Case Studies<br />

specific issues are h<strong>and</strong>led by its units <strong>and</strong> subsidiaries. Although the relationship<br />

generally is constructive, Axpo perceives exposure from the pressure that politics<br />

exerts on the regulator. As a result,a number <strong>of</strong> regulatory objectives lead to<br />

suboptimal industry developments. Politicians dem<strong>and</strong>, for example, the big-scale<br />

provision <strong>of</strong> renewable energy at low cost, which in Axpo's view is unattainable in<br />

foreseeable time (cf. interview N°6: 14). Such policy requests are mostly a result from<br />

political difficulties to accommodate the complex requirements from the industry's<br />

multi-dimensionality. In addition, the conflict between political fixation on election<br />

cycles <strong>and</strong> the long-term orientation required for energy issues are a further source <strong>of</strong><br />

political exposure.<br />

5.1.6 Axpo's embedding capabilities<br />

Given the various sources <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure, how does Axpo approach its local<br />

environment <strong>and</strong> what are its strategies towards reduction <strong>of</strong> this exposure? How does<br />

it ensure, that its activities are aligned with societal expectations, being perceived as a<br />

good corporate citizen? Due to its long experience in the Swiss market <strong>and</strong> in the<br />

different cantons where it operates, Axpo is well aware <strong>of</strong> its dependence: in our<br />

interviews with Axpo representatives, there was consensus that without the support <strong>of</strong><br />

the local stakeholders Axpo cannot maintain a successful operation. Traditionally<br />

therefore, Axpo makes significant efforts to gain operational legitimacy, furthering an<br />

ongoing dialogue between the local operation <strong>and</strong> its surrounding stakeholders. This<br />

awareness must also be seen in the light <strong>of</strong> concession renewals. Although a<br />

concession is granted for the duration <strong>of</strong> an average <strong>of</strong> 40 years, the local goodwill<br />

needed to facilitate its renewal is path-dependent <strong>and</strong> can only be accumulated over<br />

time. In order to effectively call on goodwill stocks, their accumulation therefore has<br />

to be cultivated on a continuous basis.<br />

In the following we will outline, how Axpo uses its embedding capabilities along the<br />

structure <strong>of</strong> our research framework.<br />

Capabilities towards structural local embedding. Axpo effectively makes use <strong>of</strong> its<br />

legitimisation capabilities on all three identified dimensions: (a) value share remaining<br />

in region; (b) mutual lock-in between the firm <strong>and</strong> its major stakeholders; <strong>and</strong> (c)<br />

internal governance, as will be discussed subsequently.<br />

(a) value share remaining in region. Axpo's hydropower <strong>and</strong> nuclear power assets<br />

predominantly originate from former NOK, recently rebr<strong>and</strong>ed into Axpo AG. In its<br />

early days NOK heavily invested in hydropower projects in infrastructure-weak


Case Studies<br />

regions. As a consequence, after payment <strong>of</strong> the concession fee, most <strong>of</strong> Axpo's locally<br />

generated pr<strong>of</strong>its were transferred to its homebase in Baden (canton Aargau) where it<br />

also paid taxes, i.e. little <strong>of</strong> the value created remained in the region (cf. interview N°3:<br />

6). This imbalance did not go unnoticed by the economically weaker cantons hosting<br />

its plants. Thus, over time these areas also requested a bigger share <strong>of</strong> the pr<strong>of</strong>it <strong>and</strong> in<br />

the negotiations for concession renewals Axpo had to accept a higher degree <strong>of</strong> rentappropriation.<br />

Today, Axpo is very conscious <strong>of</strong> the necessity to take, but also to give appropriately.<br />

In its project negotiations it involves all relevant stakeholders early on <strong>and</strong> displays a<br />

willingness to sacrifice part <strong>of</strong> the project's pr<strong>of</strong>itability for environmental, l<strong>and</strong>scaperelated,<br />

<strong>and</strong> social concerns in exchange for the necessary stakeholder support. Once<br />

more referring to its prime example in Linth-Limmern, Axpo succeeded to get the goahead<br />

for its mega-project in the minimum time. Among the key factors to success<br />

were 100 :<br />

- Rent transfer to the canton during construction phase: CHF 12.4m p.a. in the<br />

form <strong>of</strong> taxes, public dues, <strong>and</strong> power sales<br />

- Rent transfer to the canton in the operational phase: plus CHF 2.7m in taxes<br />

compared to previous tax-level<br />

- Secondary effects <strong>of</strong> construction investment: generation <strong>of</strong> 240 jobs, additional<br />

revenue <strong>of</strong> CHF 47m for local suppliers<br />

- Concession fees between 2007 <strong>and</strong> 2015: CHF 52m<br />

- Compensation from abdication <strong>of</strong> reversion ('Heimfallverzichtsabgeltungen'):<br />

CHF 120m<br />

- Environmental compensatory measures: agreement to three major measures, i.e.<br />

improvement <strong>of</strong> the fish habitat through various structural <strong>and</strong> procedural<br />

adaptations, scenic appreciation <strong>of</strong> the region, measures to improve fauna <strong>and</strong><br />

flora through the discontinuation <strong>of</strong> sheep grazing in specified areas.<br />

- Ab<strong>and</strong>onment <strong>of</strong> the exploitation <strong>of</strong> the Linth gorge, incl. renaturation <strong>and</strong> an<br />

increase in the residual water volume<br />

All <strong>of</strong> the above admissions go significantly beyond lip service, affecting the projects<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>and</strong> causing upfront costs. It is for this reason that Axpo was able to create<br />

a climate <strong>of</strong> cooperation <strong>and</strong> trust, becoming a respected discussion partner in a<br />

normally conflict-laden situation.<br />

100 Cf. Staatskanzlei Kanton Glarus (2007). 'Aus den Verh<strong>and</strong>lungen des Regierungsrates vom 12. Juni<br />

2007 - Volkswirtschaftliche Auswirkungen des Projekts "Linthal 2015"'. Glarus: Kanton Glarus.<br />

233


234<br />

Case Studies<br />

(b) mutual lock-in between the firm <strong>and</strong> its major stakeholders. In the case <strong>of</strong> Axpo,<br />

the mutual lock-in on the political dimension is already manifested in its ownership<br />

structure. Those areas, where Axpo predominantly is active, are also owners <strong>of</strong> the<br />

firm 101 , thus providing it with more stability <strong>and</strong> facilitating the alignment <strong>of</strong> interests.<br />

Moreover, the Axpo group was founded on the basis <strong>of</strong> the NOK founding treaty 102 ,<br />

dating back to 1914, which guarantees the firm a right <strong>of</strong> priority on water resources<br />

within the shareholding cantons. Other means to create a mutual lock-in are achieved<br />

by the creation <strong>of</strong> structural parameters through the public administration, such as the<br />

legally secured supply for local power projects. Examples are covenants to all organic<br />

waste, or rights to the wood from local forests, within a specified region for the<br />

fuelling <strong>of</strong> renewable energy plants.<br />

Beyond the ownership lock-in <strong>of</strong> its core regions, commitment in critical stakeholder<br />

relations is <strong>of</strong>ten achieved through strategic appointments to the subsidiaries'<br />

supervisory boards. Many <strong>of</strong> Axpo's power plants are part <strong>of</strong> small, mostly local legal<br />

entities, which are integrated into one <strong>of</strong> its units. <strong>The</strong> board <strong>of</strong> these entities assumes<br />

not only a governance function, but its composition is in part strategic, with hindsight<br />

to the local political environment. Axpo regularly appoints important opinion makers,<br />

politicians, or local entrepreneurs to strengthen its embedding in the region, as well as<br />

to facilitate future development schemes.<br />

(c) internal governance. Justified by the pivotal significance <strong>of</strong> energy supply for<br />

society, the latter expects transparency from Axpo in its activities. This societal<br />

expectation is further substantiated by the fact, that Axpo h<strong>and</strong>les hazardous materials<br />

(e.g. enriched uranium for its nuclear power plants), <strong>and</strong> by the impacts its operations<br />

have on the surrounding ecosystems. Axpo is aware <strong>of</strong> the need to be transparent 103<br />

<strong>and</strong> to ensure compliance with the law <strong>and</strong> its ethical st<strong>and</strong>ards. Its efforts to this effect<br />

include:<br />

- internal corporate risk management<br />

- transparency through monitoring <strong>and</strong> reporting<br />

- certifications from accredited external institutions<br />

101 <strong>The</strong> shareholding cantons are locked in by means <strong>of</strong> a shareholders' agreement.<br />

102<br />

See also §5 <strong>of</strong> the 'Vertrag zwischen den Kantonen Aargau, Glarus, Zürich, St. Gallen, Thurgau,<br />

Schaffhausen, Schwyz, Appenzell A.-Rh. und Zug vom 22. März 1914 betreffend Gründung der<br />

Gesellschaft der Nordostschweizerischen Kraftwerke AG'.<br />

103<br />

Cf. 'Das Treibhausgasinventar der Axpo'. Retrieved June 12, 2010, from Axpo corporate website:<br />

www.nachhaltigkeit.axpo.ch/axpo/de/home/verantwortung/environment/co2/axpo_treibhausgas.html.


Case Studies<br />

Axpo's risk management thereby is an integral part <strong>of</strong> the firm's corporate governance.<br />

It increases informational transparency <strong>and</strong> thus contributes to better <strong>and</strong> risk-adequate<br />

corporate decision-making. Risk considerations include the dimensions finance,<br />

security <strong>of</strong> supply, environment, <strong>and</strong> reputation. Within the organisation, Axpo's risk<br />

management is decentrally organised, but coordinated by the holding's Corporate Risk<br />

Management department. While responsibility for the risk management conception<br />

<strong>and</strong> implementation in order to establish firm-wide transparency remains with the<br />

latter, risk ownership is with the line businesses (Sangiorgio, Hottinger, & Brodbeck,<br />

2008).<br />

Aimed at strengthening its credibility with regard to sustainable power generation,<br />

Axpo continuously measures a number <strong>of</strong> indicators, which it uses for its own<br />

controlling, as well as for publication to its stakeholders. In its endeavours to decrease<br />

its CO2 contributions, Axpo for example monitors corporate-wide emissions, thus<br />

obtaining clarity on the major internal emission flows. From these insights it derives<br />

improvement-, reduction- <strong>and</strong> compensation-objectives. Furthermore, in 2010 it<br />

started with annual publications <strong>of</strong> its CO2 inventory. Another effort <strong>of</strong> trust-building<br />

is made in the reporting on its highly sensitive nuclear plant operations, for which it<br />

publishes detailed information on the respective websites. For its reactors in Beznau<br />

Axpo published a certified environmental declaration for the first time in 2009 (cf.<br />

Umweltdeklaration Kernkraftwerk Beznau. Axpo AG, 2009). Since 2007 the group<br />

produces a comprehensive sustainability report every second year, compliant to <strong>and</strong><br />

audited by the Global Reporting Initiative (GRI).<br />

As further means for trust- <strong>and</strong> reputation-building, Axpo fosters cooperations with<br />

reputable institutions (e.g. Paul Scherrer Institut, ETH) thus supporting research to<br />

improve energy efficiency. It also has engaged accredited external organisations, such<br />

as the German TÜV, to certify processes, data collection, or to validate power labels<br />

(e.g. electricity from renewable sources).<br />

Capabilities towards relational local embedding. <strong>The</strong> basis for Axpo's actions<br />

towards gaining <strong>and</strong> maintaining its 'licence to operate' is compactly summarised in<br />

the firm's policy document on sustainability (Axpo Holding AG, 2007: 9):<br />

3.4 We strive for high acceptance<br />

Our success depends on the public's trust in Axpo, which we continuously<br />

endeavour to earn <strong>and</strong> invigorate<br />

We take the expectations <strong>of</strong> the relevant interest groups seriously <strong>and</strong> take them into<br />

account in our actions<br />

235


236<br />

Case Studies<br />

3.5 We are committed to transparency<br />

<strong>The</strong> significance <strong>of</strong> energy supply for our society constitutes a societal right to<br />

transparency. We feel obliged to this right. We comply thereto by communicating<br />

openly <strong>and</strong> honestly<br />

We strive for results-oriented <strong>and</strong> holistic management, which requires<br />

transparency in leadership <strong>and</strong> in decision-making - internally as well as externally<br />

<strong>The</strong>se principles are operationalised in its daily actions on the three identified<br />

dimensions <strong>of</strong> relational embedding: (a) relational capabilities; (b) reputation-building<br />

capabilities; (c) capabilities to adapt to the local environment.<br />

(a) relational capabilities. Through the long-term orientation <strong>of</strong> its business activities<br />

<strong>and</strong> the longevity <strong>of</strong> its assets, Axpo has adopted a sustainable approach to its<br />

relationship management. On one side, it has a systematic approach in its project<br />

planning <strong>and</strong> pre-concession phases (cf. Axpo Sustainability Report 2008/2009: 50f.).<br />

Its activities embrace all relevant stakeholders, informing <strong>and</strong> exchanging with them<br />

before they go ahead with any <strong>of</strong>ficial appeal or bidding for concession. In these<br />

exchanges the firm's managers are aware, that sensitivities against new projects <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

are <strong>of</strong> emotional nature, not susceptible to rational reasoning. <strong>The</strong> success <strong>of</strong> their<br />

approach therefore is as much contingent on their empathy towards these stakeholders<br />

<strong>and</strong> their underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> stakeholder expectations <strong>and</strong> fears, as it depends on the<br />

project-related facts. Axpo makes use <strong>of</strong> the following platforms for stakeholder<br />

communication in the pre-concession phase:<br />

- information sessions in the municipal assemblies to inform on the planned scale<br />

<strong>of</strong> project, as well as on impacts on the local environment <strong>and</strong> eco-system<br />

(target group: politicians, local community)<br />

- public hearings for questions <strong>and</strong> answers on the project (target group: local<br />

community)<br />

- cooperation with a local bridging party, i.e. parties with an inherent interest in<br />

the project's implementation, in order to reduce liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness104<br />

(target groups: reduces exposure versus politicians, public administration,<br />

interest groups)<br />

- establishment <strong>of</strong> work groups to assess sensitive issues <strong>and</strong> compensatory<br />

measures (target groups: public administration, regulator, interest groups)<br />

104<br />

Axpo experiences liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness even on Swiss territory, outside its founding cantons,<br />

where preference is <strong>of</strong>ten given to the local utility (cf. interviews N°3: 21; N°1: 15).


Case Studies<br />

On the other side, its platforms which it regularly uses during the operational phase<br />

are:<br />

- information sessions <strong>and</strong> hearings in front <strong>of</strong> the municipal assemblies,<br />

periodically <strong>and</strong> not only in the face <strong>of</strong> critical issues (target group: politicians,<br />

local administration, local community)<br />

- open house days in local power plants (target group: local community)<br />

- exchange <strong>and</strong> sensitisation on current local issues via the local members <strong>of</strong> the<br />

board (reducing exposure towards politicians, local administration)<br />

- local initiatives to familiarise the local community with the firm <strong>and</strong> its<br />

activities<br />

By being familiar with the people, the environment, <strong>and</strong> Axpo's assets, the firm's<br />

representatives achieve high efficiency in their daily tasks, but also in the assessment<br />

<strong>of</strong> singular situations, allowing for short reaction-times <strong>and</strong> fast decisions (cf.<br />

interview N°4: 6). In addition, Axpo systematically uses synergies in their relations<br />

with the local key-decision makers. If one unit already has well-working contacts <strong>and</strong><br />

another unit wants to become active in the region, it draws on the existing contacts<br />

from the unit which is already locally present.<br />

For the illustration <strong>of</strong> Axpo's relational embedding capabilities, we refer once more to<br />

the Linth-Limmern project. Very early in its planning process Axpo invited all<br />

relevant interest groups, thus signalling its serious intentions to actively involve the<br />

invited parties. As a consequence, despite reservations against the scale <strong>and</strong> design <strong>of</strong><br />

the project, the associations recognised their opportunity to constructively secure their<br />

interests. Among the involved were the cantonal department for environmental<br />

protection, the WWF, the local fishery association, <strong>and</strong> the Swiss l<strong>and</strong>scape<br />

conservation foundation 105 . Together they defined the compensatory measures for the<br />

project, which were approved by the canton's governing council. Not only did the<br />

parties find a common denominator, it also helped to align interests as to obtain a<br />

maximum result with the available funds for compensatory measures. While Axpo<br />

initially designed a type <strong>of</strong> dam wall which focused on low visibility for ecological<br />

reasons, it became clear in the course <strong>of</strong> the discussion, that the environmental<br />

authorities were more concerned with residual water <strong>and</strong> perceived no benefit from the<br />

more expensive construction type. Thus, Axpo was able to design a less costly dam,<br />

while being able to make concessions with regard to other environmental concerns (cf.<br />

interview N°1: 21).<br />

105 I.e. Stiftung L<strong>and</strong>schaftsschutz Schweiz.<br />

237


238<br />

Case Studies<br />

(b) reputation-building capabilities. In addition to relationship-building with its direct<br />

stakeholders, Axpo invests in a number <strong>of</strong> activities to strengthen its reputation as a<br />

good corporate citizen. Its engagement spans the dimensions<br />

- environment: e.g. cooperation with the Swiss Alpine Club (SAC) for the<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> energy-efficient projects, or funding <strong>of</strong> a research project on<br />

the impact <strong>of</strong> climate change on Swiss glaciers;<br />

- society: e.g. various educational projects, financial support <strong>of</strong> socially<br />

disadvantaged people, etc.;<br />

- sustainability: commitment to sustainability in its activities by anchoring it in<br />

Axpo's company strategy as a social responsibility; <strong>and</strong><br />

- employment: 350 positions for vocational training.<br />

A major effect <strong>of</strong> all <strong>of</strong> these engagements undoubtedly is trust-building, which is the<br />

basis for successful local interactions, or as a representative <strong>of</strong> Axpo AG's<br />

management puts it: “trust is essential - if the region trusts, that Axpo builds its assets<br />

for the common good <strong>of</strong> the local community, the quality <strong>of</strong> the cooperation improves<br />

significantly” (interview N°4: 17). On the national level, trust-building with the<br />

regulator <strong>and</strong> nationally organised interest groups is essential. For this reason, Axpo<br />

co-founded the 'Energy Trialogue', establishing a dialogue between industry<br />

regulators, power utilities, environmental interest groups, <strong>and</strong> research institutions to<br />

give impulses for a sustainable <strong>and</strong> competitive energy policy in Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, thus<br />

constructively contributing to the directions <strong>of</strong> the future regulatory set-up.<br />

Importantly, the fragility <strong>of</strong> trust <strong>and</strong> reputation is demonstrated by Greenpeace's<br />

recent questioning <strong>of</strong> the declaration <strong>of</strong> origin that Axpo has made for its enriched<br />

uranium resources. To regain public trust in the firm's communication, particularly the<br />

criticised life-cycle assessment, Axpo has reacted immediately: after obtaining more<br />

precise data, it corrected the contested figures <strong>and</strong> initiated a re-certification <strong>of</strong> the<br />

respective plant <strong>and</strong> document. <strong>The</strong> fact, that Greenpeace has chosen to address the<br />

public <strong>and</strong> the resulting echo in the media, is another indication <strong>of</strong> the industry's<br />

exposure <strong>and</strong> the population's sensitivity towards electric utilities.<br />

(c) capabilities to adapt to the local environment. As already described, Axpo's efforts<br />

to adapt to the local environment are <strong>of</strong>ten supported by local gatekeepers. Through<br />

their engagement for the firm, Axpo has the unique opportunity to learn about<br />

potential issues, before they become one. Thus, the firm can act in time, signalling its<br />

willingness to cooperate, or inform stakeholders before misunderst<strong>and</strong>ings arise. By<br />

appointing local politicians to the local unit's board, an additional channel for


Case Studies<br />

information exchange <strong>and</strong> influence is established. In combination, the local unit is<br />

knowledgeable on specific stakeholder expectations, whose adherence are a<br />

precondition to legitimisation <strong>and</strong> embedding. As a consequence, even though Axpo is<br />

perceived as a sizeable Aargau-based firm, by the local identity <strong>of</strong> its subsidiaries it<br />

reduces its liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness.<br />

5.1.7 Value creation<br />

As in the framework, we will analyse value creation at Axpo on two levels: (1) from a<br />

single-site perspective on the local level, as well as (2) from the multi-site perspective,<br />

having a closer look at Axpo's overall fields <strong>of</strong> value creation.<br />

(1) single-site perspective. Inferred from prior observations in section 5.1.6, Axpo's<br />

local embedding leads to value creation opportunities for its sub-units <strong>and</strong> individual<br />

power plants. In their long-term fostering <strong>of</strong> stakeholder relationships <strong>and</strong> cooperation<br />

with authorities, Axpo's subunits have been able to secure a number <strong>of</strong> options for<br />

their business development. In the case <strong>of</strong> the Linth-Limmern project, the local<br />

subsidiary's 106 sustained local presence in Linthal was decisive, combined with its<br />

continuous lobbying <strong>and</strong> its cultivation <strong>of</strong> constructive stakeholder-dialogues long<br />

before the project came up (cf. interview N°3: 13f.). Particularly its connectedness<br />

with the regional political representatives helped an efficient information flow, beyond<br />

the <strong>of</strong>ficial channels <strong>and</strong> processes. Consequently, important details were exchanged<br />

faster, <strong>and</strong> with less red tape, speeding up the efficient finalisation <strong>of</strong> the project<br />

application. In absence <strong>of</strong> these factors, the agreement-finding process with its critical<br />

stakeholders very likely would have taken longer, or would not have come to<br />

conclusion at all.<br />

Similarly in other projects, its subsidiaries' <strong>and</strong> local units' awareness, sensitivity <strong>and</strong><br />

incessant efforts to build social capital are one <strong>of</strong> the firm's key success factors for<br />

project implementation. In this sense, the local unit's embedding capabilities create<br />

strategic options <strong>and</strong> business development opportunities, which a firm with less<br />

developed embedding skills <strong>and</strong> organisational legitimacy would not be able to create.<br />

Moreover, the established links with the local environment serve as a protection <strong>of</strong> the<br />

local assets. Despite the fact that water concessions have to be 'bought' with<br />

appeasement measures, the return <strong>of</strong> such measures comes in the form <strong>of</strong> decreased<br />

project risk, thus protecting the firm's sunk cost investment. <strong>The</strong> high legitimisation <strong>of</strong><br />

Axpo's power plants in their local environments increases the chances <strong>of</strong> cost<br />

106 Kraftwerke Linth-Limmern AG (KLL).<br />

239


240<br />

Case Studies<br />

repayment over their lifetime - even under the sacrifice <strong>of</strong> slightly deferred break-even<br />

points. Because many plants are situated in infrastructure-weak regions, not only Axpo<br />

relies on the cooperation <strong>of</strong> the region, but the region is also dependent on the plant's<br />

fees <strong>and</strong> taxes, employment, as well as its secondary economic effects (cf. '(a) value<br />

share remaining in region', p.232). <strong>The</strong>refore, despite the conflicting interests on rent<br />

appropriation, the region will ensure that the basic economic prerequisites for the firm<br />

are sound.<br />

In addition, Axpo benefits from reduced risks <strong>of</strong> competition through the strong local<br />

mooring <strong>of</strong> its subunits, which serves as a protective mobility barrier in face <strong>of</strong> the<br />

impending full market liberalisation. Not only is Axpo a Swiss power producer, but it<br />

draws additional legitimacy from its comparably 'clean' energy mix <strong>and</strong> its<br />

contribution to the local economies. As a member <strong>of</strong> Axpo's executive board puts it:<br />

Through its regional embedding Axpo presumably has an advantage over<br />

foreign suppliers. Consequently, liberalisation provides us with a potential to<br />

sell power at long-distance all over Europe, while we experience no<br />

disadvantage from our being tied to Swiss locations. (interview N°3: 5)<br />

On another scale, Axpo is able to lower risks on the supply-side by securing<br />

continuous replenishment <strong>of</strong> renewable fuels through contracts with the regional<br />

public administration, as mentioned before. Such secured supply serves as another<br />

protection <strong>of</strong> its investment.<br />

In the short term Axpo's subsidiaries create value through their legitimisation<br />

capabilities on the identified dimensions:<br />

- Transaction costs: through its manifold informal interactions with stakeholders on<br />

a local, regional <strong>and</strong> national level, Axpo is able to lower its transaction costs<br />

significantly. On the one h<strong>and</strong> it increases its chances for a faster agreement with<br />

the involved parties in projects, thus saving time, as has been demonstrated in the<br />

case <strong>of</strong> Linth-Limmern. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, it is able to lower expenses in its<br />

interactions with the public administration, by avoiding exhausting legal<br />

proceedings from conflicts with interest group stakeholders, <strong>and</strong> by means <strong>of</strong><br />

private ordering in general. Exemplary for its reduction <strong>of</strong> transaction costs through<br />

embedding capabilities are Axpo's operations in the Surselva region in Grisons.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re, Axpo is locally embedded through its subsidiary Axpo Hydro Surselva AG<br />

(HS AG). <strong>The</strong> unit is possibly the biggest economic contributor to the region <strong>and</strong><br />

has a predominantly local workforce, loyal to the firm. <strong>The</strong> resulting goodwill<br />

stock in the region helps to reduce transaction costs in the daily business <strong>and</strong>


Case Studies<br />

particularly in permitting issues, as exemplified by HS AG's replacement <strong>of</strong> its<br />

hydroelectric turbines. For road transportation <strong>of</strong> these turbines special permits are<br />

required, due to their size. Each local municipality thus needs to give approval for<br />

the respective road sections, based on a formal request. HS AG was able to obtain<br />

all <strong>of</strong> the permits at a minimum level <strong>of</strong> administrative expense, based on the<br />

established relationship between the firm <strong>and</strong> its local administrations. This kind <strong>of</strong><br />

pragmatic cooperation generally characterises HS AGs relation to its institutional<br />

environment.<br />

In addition, Axpo's policy to only invest in projects, if the local community backs<br />

them, equally results in transaction cost savings. As the case <strong>of</strong> Würenlingen has<br />

shown, Axpo's decision to consequentially withdraw from controversial projects is<br />

an important part <strong>of</strong> a firm's legitimisation capabilities. Possessing the aptitude to<br />

ab<strong>and</strong>on a project in cases <strong>of</strong> strong opposition in order to protect the overall<br />

reputation <strong>of</strong> the firm also saves costs <strong>and</strong> negative legitimacy spillovers 107 .<br />

- Operational efficiency: the local embeddedness <strong>of</strong> its subsidiaries also entails<br />

opportunities for increased operational efficiency, as demonstrated by Axpo's<br />

partner plant Kraftwerke Maggia AG. Located in the rather remote region <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Maggia valley (Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, canton Tessin) the firm is an important economic<br />

factor for the local population. Thus, goodwill stocks <strong>of</strong> all local stakeholders are<br />

historically high, which also made it possible that the firm obtained permits for six<br />

power plants that are controlled to serially exploit the hydropower from the valley's<br />

gradient. Thus, Kraftwerke Maggia AG is not only able to optimally use the<br />

valley's hydropower potential, but also to realise synergies from its local<br />

workforce. With almost the same number <strong>of</strong> specialised employees that would be<br />

necessary for a smaller number <strong>of</strong> plant operations, it efficiently maintains <strong>and</strong><br />

controls six plants, which reduces its operational costs. Similarly, Axpo Hydro<br />

Surselva AG serially exploits hydropower through eight plants, a constellation<br />

which also became possible through its high local embeddedness.<br />

107 In contrast, the case <strong>of</strong> the project by Kraftwerke Oberhasli AG in the Grimsel region demonstrates<br />

how the adherence to controversial implementation schemes can become costly, in terms <strong>of</strong> time to<br />

implementation <strong>and</strong> legal costs. KWO states in its first sustainability report (2009: 47): "Der Konflikt<br />

um 'Grimsel West' traf die KWO unvorbereitet. Das Unternehmen reagierte auf die vorgebrachte<br />

Kritik hauptsächlich abweisend und begegnete verschiedenen Exponenten der Opposition mit<br />

politischem Druck. Der Konflikt nahm im Laufe der Jahre nationale Dimensionen an. Die Fronten<br />

verhärteten sich zusehends."<br />

241


242<br />

Case Studies<br />

- Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> financial processes: Axpo's subsidiaries contribute to lower<br />

financing cost, due to investors' trust on the basis <strong>of</strong> their track records in daily<br />

operation, project implementation <strong>and</strong> their local legitimacy. If investors know,<br />

that Axpo has the necessary local acceptance to follow through with planned<br />

projects, the willingness to invest in such schemes is higher. In addition, fewer<br />

bank guarantees are necessary <strong>and</strong> suppliers are more flexible with regard to late<br />

payments in case <strong>of</strong> temporary distress <strong>of</strong> a project, thus resulting in lower default<br />

interests.<br />

- Exploitation <strong>of</strong> positive externalities: many <strong>of</strong> Axpo's power production<br />

technologies produce by-products, such as heat. <strong>The</strong> ability to create opportunities<br />

for their exploitation substantially depends on the firm's regional legitimacy. For its<br />

nuclear power plant in Beznau (Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, canton Aargau), Axpo was able to<br />

establish a long-distance heating network, managed by the separate legal entity<br />

REFUNA. Today REFUNA supplies nine neighbouring municipalities <strong>and</strong> 2'500<br />

connections. <strong>The</strong> project's implementation, from the idea to the commissioning <strong>of</strong><br />

the first parts <strong>of</strong> the network took almost nine years <strong>of</strong> research <strong>and</strong> intensive<br />

negotiations, requiring refined political skills 108 . <strong>The</strong> fact, that REFUNA came into<br />

life <strong>and</strong> is able to exp<strong>and</strong> its reach ever since can be declared a success story. Many<br />

other projects (e.g. the envisaged networks TRANSWAL, WARHENO, FOLA),<br />

which were envisaged at the time failed, among other factors, due to a combination<br />

<strong>of</strong> uncompetitive pricing <strong>and</strong> insufficient underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the political processes<br />

(cf. Graf, H<strong>and</strong>l, & Pritzker, 2004). Another example for the cooperative<br />

exploitation <strong>of</strong> by-products can be found in the renewable energy unit, where<br />

organic waste generates biogas, electricity, long-distance heating for neighbouring<br />

households, <strong>and</strong> marketable fertilizer. <strong>The</strong>se externalities are <strong>of</strong>ten exploited<br />

through the cooperation with local partners, such as composting plants <strong>and</strong> sewage<br />

plants, <strong>and</strong> by selling them to local farmers.<br />

(2) multi-site perspective. In the management <strong>of</strong> its several subsidiaries <strong>and</strong> dozens <strong>of</strong><br />

sites, the role <strong>of</strong> Axpo's holding is primarily financial, subsumed in the responsibility<br />

to determine the overall strategic direction, to monitor the progress <strong>of</strong> strategy<br />

implementation, to raise capital efficiently, <strong>and</strong> to effectively engage in political<br />

lobbying. In its underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> leadership, the holding recognises the significance <strong>of</strong><br />

being familiar with the local facts <strong>and</strong> circumstances. <strong>The</strong>refore it mainly engages on a<br />

group level, leaving local decisions to the local management.<br />

108 In addition, the second oil crisis <strong>and</strong> a rising environmental awareness helped the project's take-<strong>of</strong>f.


Case Studies<br />

In addition to its strategic tasks the Axpo group creates value along the dimensions (a)<br />

relations, (b) resources, <strong>and</strong> (c) institutions <strong>of</strong> the presented framework, as illustrated<br />

below.<br />

(a) relations. As the empirical research indicates, Axpo's emerging br<strong>and</strong>, the group's<br />

size <strong>and</strong> its industry competence are valuable factors in the bidding <strong>and</strong> negotiation<br />

processes <strong>of</strong> its subsidiaries, as well as in its local units' daily operations. On one side,<br />

through positive spillovers the group's reputation proves advantageous to business<br />

units <strong>and</strong> smaller subsidiaries in their local interactions. On the other side, Axpo's size<br />

shields BU's from opportunistic stakeholder behaviour in negotiation <strong>and</strong> bidding<br />

phases, since it has the capacity <strong>and</strong> means to walk away, if the <strong>of</strong>fered conditions are<br />

economically unviable.<br />

On the level <strong>of</strong> inter-unit cooperation, Axpo's individual units very effectively exploit<br />

synergies from their local embeddedness. In cases where one unit is firmly established,<br />

other units with upcoming projects or activities in the region approach the existing unit<br />

to benefit from its contacts with the local authorities <strong>and</strong> other stakeholders (cf.<br />

interview N°1: 11). For example, the scope <strong>of</strong> the Linth-Limmern project includes also<br />

a new extra-high voltage connection to the Swiss transmission network. Since Axpo's<br />

local subsidiary KLL knows all relevant stakeholders, the experts from the grid unit<br />

closely work with KLL in order to facilitate their local relationship building. <strong>The</strong><br />

support from the local unit thus helps to speed up processes <strong>and</strong> to save transaction<br />

costs.<br />

(b) resources. According to insights from the empirical research Axpo's subsidiaries<br />

have no established lateral exchange. Interactions mostly take place hierarchically via<br />

the group level. <strong>The</strong> same applies further down the hierarchy, within Axpo AG's units<br />

<strong>and</strong> their respective subsidiaries <strong>and</strong> plants. With the objective to establish firm-wide<br />

minimum st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>and</strong> to ensure governance, emphasis lies on subjects, such as work<br />

safety, operational safety, reliability, or security <strong>of</strong> supply. Simultaneously, Axpo<br />

becomes more efficient in the implementation <strong>of</strong> regulatory st<strong>and</strong>ards through the<br />

pace-setting role <strong>of</strong> the holding level. In addition, the company realises cost<br />

advantages by st<strong>and</strong>ardising best practice maintenance procedures, thus shortening<br />

downtimes from maintenance activities <strong>and</strong> increasing the asset's overall utilisation.<br />

Through coordination between its operational entities, Axpo as a holding is able to<br />

realise a number <strong>of</strong> operational synergies. <strong>The</strong>y are generated on all organisational<br />

levels, as illustrated by the examples in the subsequent table.<br />

243


244<br />

Type <strong>of</strong><br />

synergy<br />

operative<br />

synergies<br />

market<br />

power<br />

synergies<br />

Organisat.<br />

level<br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel;<br />

BU level<br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel;<br />

BU level<br />

cross-sitelevel<br />

Examples<br />

Case Studies<br />

Economies <strong>of</strong> scope through the group's multiple power generation<br />

sources. Due to Axpo's mix in electricity generation, it is able to<br />

optimise its overall capacity utilisation in spite <strong>of</strong> the peak-load problem<br />

characteristic to power utilities. Its hydropower plants, including a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> reservoirs <strong>and</strong> pumped-storage plants, allow for exact<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>-based planning <strong>of</strong> power production, <strong>and</strong> to exploit the base<br />

loads <strong>of</strong> its nuclear power plants. Axpo even sources excess electricity<br />

from French nuclear plants <strong>and</strong> German wind-parks at low cost, using it<br />

for pump-storing its water resources to produce high-priced peak-load<br />

power at a later point. <strong>The</strong>se opportunities are not available to single-site<br />

operations, or to firms without a balanced energy mix.<br />

Economies <strong>of</strong> scale in the firm's support activities, such as HR, finance,<br />

marketing, public affairs, political affairs <strong>and</strong> regulatory lobbying.<br />

Economies <strong>of</strong> scale with regard to electricity trading. Through its size<br />

Axpo is able to realise growth <strong>and</strong> volume synergies in trading, which<br />

are crucial due to the trend towards decreasing margins per deal.<br />

Economies <strong>of</strong> experience within the individual lines <strong>of</strong> production<br />

(grids, trading, hydro power, nuclear power, or renewable energies), e.g.<br />

in the planning <strong>and</strong> conception <strong>of</strong> assets, but also in daily operation.<br />

Best practice exchange across sites within BU's, on an expert-level. This<br />

exchange is not institutionalised, but happens on a need-basis.<br />

BU level Value is created particularly in the optimisation <strong>of</strong> maintenance<br />

procedures (cf. interview N°4: 6), but also in the fields <strong>of</strong> work safety<br />

<strong>and</strong> operational safety, as well as regulatory compliance.<br />

grouplevel;<br />

BU level<br />

grouplevel<br />

(continued next page)<br />

Efficiency synergies through joint use <strong>of</strong> assets. Particularly in the field<br />

<strong>of</strong> IT, infrastructure <strong>and</strong> licences are jointly used; otherwise very limited<br />

use <strong>of</strong> joint mobile assets for the operation <strong>and</strong> maintenance <strong>of</strong><br />

transmission grids.<br />

Joint purchasing or critical resources (e.g. nuclear fuel, components,<br />

plants <strong>and</strong> facilities, but also IT hardware <strong>and</strong> services).<br />

BU level By selling electricity centrally to the communal end distribution utilities,<br />

Axpo AG is able to achieve market conditions, which would not be<br />

attainable to its individual subsidiaries.


Case Studies<br />

Type <strong>of</strong><br />

synergy<br />

financial<br />

synergies<br />

corporate<br />

mgmt.<br />

synergies<br />

Organisat.<br />

level<br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel<br />

Examples<br />

Table 5-3: Overview on Axpo's synergy implementation<br />

Financial economies <strong>of</strong> scale through efficient overall capital raising.<br />

For the first time since its founding in 2001 Axpo has issued bonds<br />

amounting to CHF 1 bn in 2010, with the objective to finance upcoming<br />

large investments in its power plants <strong>and</strong> grid infrastructure.<br />

Increased financial flexibility through a balanced business portfolio.<br />

Thus, Axpo is able to set investment priorities according to future<br />

strategic directions, without being reliant on the external capital market.<br />

While renewable energies currently need more funding to grow than<br />

they can contribute from their own resources, many hydropower plants<br />

are highly pr<strong>of</strong>itable, since they reach the last third <strong>of</strong> their lifecycle<br />

beyond their payback period. Thus, financial resources can be shifted<br />

accordingly.<br />

Reduced corporate risk due to the complementarities <strong>of</strong> hydro-power<br />

<strong>and</strong> nuclear power. In contrast, if each <strong>of</strong> these asset parks were<br />

regarded individually, they would represent a cluster risk to the firm.<br />

As a group, Axpo enjoys holding privileges reducing its overall tax<br />

burden.<br />

With the help <strong>of</strong> the group's financial planning <strong>and</strong> allocational<br />

capabilities, it fosters the business units' entrepreneurial capabilities <strong>and</strong><br />

supports the implementation <strong>of</strong> the envisioned strategy. In the field <strong>of</strong><br />

renewable energy, for example, the holding identified it as a strategic<br />

field for growth, consequently allocating financial means to the<br />

responsible unit. This in turn enables the BU to develop <strong>and</strong> grow.<br />

In its holding function Axpo defines the firm's overall direction top<br />

down, which its units consequently break down into concrete objectives<br />

through a bottom up process.<br />

(c) institutions. As a function <strong>of</strong> Axpo's size in the Swiss electricity market, the group<br />

has incomparably more possibilities for effective regulatory lobbying, compared to its<br />

units, individual subsidiaries, <strong>and</strong> sites. Politics have a significant influence on the<br />

industry, its regulation, as well as the awarding <strong>of</strong> concessions. This influence always<br />

implies some degree <strong>of</strong> discretion in decision-making processes, regulatory<br />

developments, <strong>and</strong> the interpretation <strong>of</strong> rules <strong>and</strong> regulations (cf. interview N°6: 7).<br />

<strong>The</strong>refore Axpo ascribes high importance to its h<strong>and</strong>ling <strong>of</strong> political affairs, as well as<br />

its corporate communications. Most importantly, Axpo influences its reputation<br />

through its daily actions <strong>and</strong> its external communication, which needs to be consistent<br />

<strong>and</strong> in line with these actions. In addition, the holding is politically well connected<br />

with its channels <strong>of</strong> influence, among others, including<br />

245


246<br />

Case Studies<br />

- direct <strong>and</strong> informal interaction <strong>of</strong> top management with the country's federal<br />

councillors in urgent matters,<br />

- regular formal meetings with federal councillors,<br />

- engagement <strong>of</strong> two lobbyists in the federal parliament in Berne,<br />

- participation in various industry-relevant committees <strong>and</strong> panels (e.g. Energy<br />

Trialogue),<br />

- relationship management with the regulatory bodies through public affairs<br />

department <strong>and</strong> regulatory managers, <strong>and</strong><br />

- participation in industry associations (e.g. VSE, Swisselectric),<br />

in order to actively shape Swiss energy policy (cf. interviews N°3: 13; N°4: 20). Apart<br />

from the influence on policy making, these engagements also help to lower the group's<br />

transaction costs.<br />

With regard to compliance monitoring, Axpo's risk management to retain an overview<br />

from the holding perspective, as well as its st<strong>and</strong>ardisation efforts to ensure<br />

compliance are a further value-creating activity. <strong>The</strong> contributions hereby lie in a risk<br />

reduction with regard to regulatory compliance, as well as in its superior capabilities to<br />

influence the regulatory developments in its interest. Both result in a lower exposure<br />

towards the regulatory bodies, protecting its going concern.<br />

5.1.8 Summary<br />

Axpo may be considered as location fixed from an upstream, as well as an ownership<br />

perspective, <strong>and</strong> to a lesser degree from a downstream perspective. <strong>The</strong> firm has a high<br />

level <strong>of</strong> consciousness on the importance <strong>of</strong> local embedding <strong>and</strong> the related activities,<br />

in particular with regard to the approval <strong>of</strong> new projects <strong>and</strong> renewal <strong>of</strong> concessions.<br />

On a single site level, the firm is actively <strong>and</strong> early involving its relevant stakeholder,<br />

with a focus on the public stakeholders <strong>and</strong> special interest groups. From a multi-unit<br />

perspective, Axpo considers itself as a financial holding, which does not interfere in<br />

the daily operation <strong>of</strong> its sub-units. Instead, it focuses on the setting <strong>of</strong> top-down<br />

strategic targets, the realisation <strong>of</strong> synergies with regard to financial markets or<br />

procurement <strong>of</strong> strategic inputs, as well as the safeguarding <strong>of</strong> regulatory compliance.<br />

On a national level, Axpo is also very active with regard to lobbying, thus taking<br />

influence on Switzerl<strong>and</strong>'s energy policy <strong>and</strong> lowering its overall transaction costs.


Case Studies<br />

5.2 Case study - airport industry<br />

Strategically important for regional <strong>and</strong> national economies the airport industry has<br />

been state-dominated over long periods <strong>of</strong> its history. Protectionism in the form <strong>of</strong><br />

heavy regulation, ownership restrictions <strong>and</strong> limits to movements in international air<br />

transportation made international engagements for both, airlines <strong>and</strong> airport operators,<br />

nearly impossible. In 1997 these conditions changed markedly with the lifting <strong>of</strong> the<br />

bilateral traffic agreements in Europe. <strong>The</strong> deregulation <strong>of</strong> the European Union's<br />

airspace led to the boom <strong>of</strong> 'budget' airlines on shorter routes <strong>and</strong> in some countries to<br />

the privatisation <strong>of</strong> the national incumbent airlines, thus allowing them more freedom<br />

to grow <strong>and</strong> exp<strong>and</strong> internationally. During this period <strong>and</strong> as a consequence <strong>of</strong> the<br />

dynamics in the airline sector, also the structure <strong>of</strong> the airport industry began to<br />

change. <strong>The</strong>se industry changes were facilitated by the fact that many states were<br />

overstrained with the financing <strong>of</strong> their airports' infrastructure modernisation <strong>and</strong> their<br />

transition to efficient customer-oriented service organisations. Consequently,<br />

governments started to deregulate <strong>and</strong> privatise the industry, combined with new<br />

regulatory approaches <strong>and</strong> models <strong>of</strong> airport management. Today, many airports are<br />

operated under public private partnerships (PPP), which leave the state with some<br />

degree <strong>of</strong> control on its strategic infrastructure, while large parts <strong>of</strong> the airport<br />

financing, planning <strong>and</strong> management is in the h<strong>and</strong>s <strong>of</strong> a private airport operator.<br />

5.2.1 Industry characteristics<br />

Airports are the most stable component in the aviation sector. <strong>The</strong>ir stability grounds<br />

on the significance <strong>of</strong> their commercial (i.e. non-aeronautical) activities, their limited<br />

competition in metropolitan areas; the persistent entry barriers based on cost,<br />

environmental, <strong>and</strong> political issues; <strong>and</strong> on regulatory mechanisms that <strong>of</strong>ten insulate<br />

airports from the airline industry's volatility. Despite the long history <strong>of</strong> the airport<br />

industry, their real commercial potential only became apparent in the process <strong>of</strong><br />

deregulation <strong>and</strong> privatisation, when they turned from mere public utilities to a<br />

commercialised industry. Nowadays, airports are more than just infrastructure for the<br />

h<strong>and</strong>ling <strong>of</strong> aircraft movements <strong>and</strong> passenger flows. Airport operators are real estate<br />

developers <strong>and</strong> builders <strong>of</strong> airport cities, they integrate business parks <strong>and</strong> shopping<br />

centres, <strong>and</strong> they provide all kinds <strong>of</strong> services that ease travelling. Because airports are<br />

natural focal points for large flows <strong>of</strong> people every day - i.e. passengers, their<br />

accompanying friends <strong>and</strong> relatives, but also employees <strong>and</strong> people otherwise<br />

transferring through the airport's facilities - they generally are attractive places for<br />

business. Thus, the industry's revenues have grown over proportionally since<br />

247


248<br />

Case Studies<br />

privatisation started, with an increasing share <strong>of</strong> commercial revenues compared to<br />

aeronautical revenues. In 2007 the average share <strong>of</strong> airports' commercial revenues was<br />

48% <strong>of</strong> overall revenues (Graham, 2009), with the best airports achieving a share <strong>of</strong> up<br />

to 58% (A.T. Kearney, 2008).<br />

As an effect <strong>of</strong> the increased commercialisation <strong>and</strong> industry dynamics, airports have<br />

not only become more efficient in the h<strong>and</strong>ling <strong>of</strong> their local passengers, but have also<br />

identified additional growth opportunities beyond their original catchment areas. This<br />

is partly a result <strong>of</strong> the hubbing strategies <strong>of</strong> their home carriers (i.e. an airport's<br />

dominant airline), but also due to its own marketing efforts to attract new airlines <strong>and</strong><br />

passengers.<br />

Traditionally airports used to be either st<strong>and</strong>-alone businesses, or they were under the<br />

auspices <strong>and</strong> management <strong>of</strong> a national state-owned airport authority. This industry<br />

structure is currently undergoing significant change through the global trend towards<br />

airport privatisation. With the UK as a forerunner, which privatised its major airports<br />

in 1987 through the formation <strong>of</strong> BAA, other privatisation initiatives began in the<br />

course <strong>of</strong> the 1990s. Figure 5-5 provides an overview <strong>of</strong> the most important airport<br />

privatisations in the past two decades.<br />

BAA<br />

Lon. City<br />

‘87 ‘92 ‘93 ‘94 ‘95 ‘96 ‘97 ‘98 ‘99 ‘00 ‘01 ‘02 ‘03 ‘04 ‘05 ‘06 ‘07 ‘08 ‘09 ‘10<br />

Vienna I<br />

Cardiff<br />

Prestwick<br />

Copenhagen I Vienna II<br />

East Midl<strong>and</strong>s Lon. City II<br />

Sheffield<br />

Belfast Int.<br />

Athens<br />

Copenhagen II<br />

Belfast Int.<br />

Xiamen<br />

Australia I<br />

Düsseldorf<br />

Rome I<br />

Istanbul<br />

Birmingham<br />

Kent Int.<br />

Mexico<br />

II<br />

Malaysia<br />

Argentina Zurich<br />

Auckl<strong>and</strong> Hamburg<br />

Skavsta Mexico II<br />

Australia II Rome II<br />

Hannover Turin<br />

Naples Newcastle<br />

South Africa<br />

London Luton<br />

Wellington<br />

Mexico I<br />

Shanghai<br />

Beijing<br />

Fraport<br />

Newcastle<br />

Lon. Luton II<br />

Bristol<br />

Birmingham<br />

Bournemouth<br />

East Midl<strong>and</strong>s II<br />

Sydney I<br />

Hainan<br />

Sydney II<br />

Belfast City<br />

Teesside<br />

Senai<br />

Figure 5-5: Chronology <strong>of</strong> airport privatisations & transactions 109<br />

Brussels<br />

TBI<br />

Tirana<br />

Blackpool<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong><br />

Argentina II<br />

Lon. Luton III<br />

Cardiff<br />

Exeter<br />

Bangalore<br />

Mumbai<br />

Budapest<br />

London City<br />

Hamburg<br />

BAA<br />

AdP<br />

GAP, Mexico<br />

Mumbai<br />

New Delhi<br />

Aberdeen<br />

Bristol<br />

Fraport<br />

Exeter<br />

Friedrichshafen<br />

Budapest<br />

AdR<br />

Birmingham<br />

Leeds Bradford<br />

Xian Xianyang Cairns<br />

TAV Lon. Gatwick<br />

Treviso Bristol<br />

Brisbane<br />

Mackay<br />

Lon. City<br />

Belfast City<br />

Blackpool<br />

London<br />

Gatwick<br />

Peel Airports<br />

Malé<br />

<strong>The</strong> trend towards airport privatisation is expected to continue, since many countries<br />

are only starting to privatise their airport infrastructure. A.T. Kearney (2008) estimates<br />

the annual transaction volume for the sale <strong>and</strong> privatisation <strong>of</strong> airports to EUR 6-8bn<br />

109 On the basis <strong>of</strong> Brown & Lee, 2010.


Case Studies<br />

until 2013 <strong>and</strong> further. As a result <strong>of</strong> the past developments <strong>and</strong> the future outlook a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> international airport management groups have emerged, which engage in<br />

the financing, consulting, operation <strong>and</strong> maintenance <strong>of</strong> airports on a global scale.<br />

Currently the major international airport operators are Fraport AG, Germany;<br />

Aéroports de Paris, France; TAV Airports Holding, Turkey; Vancouver Airport<br />

Services, Canada; Changi Airports International, Singapore; Malaysia Airport<br />

Holdings Berhad, Malaysia; GMR Group, India; <strong>and</strong> Zurich Airport (Flughafen Zürich<br />

AG), Switzerl<strong>and</strong>.<br />

In addition a number <strong>of</strong> international airport investors with a banking, venture capital,<br />

or construction background are actively seeking investment opportunities, as for<br />

example Macquarie Airports (Map), a spin-<strong>of</strong>f from the Australian Macquarie bank, or<br />

Germany's Hochtief Airport AG, as well as Spanish Ferrovial <strong>and</strong> Abertis Group,<br />

originating from the construction sector.<br />

5.2.2 Swiss airport industry<br />

Due to its small size Switzerl<strong>and</strong> has only three national commercial airports, listed in<br />

the order <strong>of</strong> their size:<br />

- Zurich Airport (21.9m passengers annually, 2009)<br />

- Geneva Airport (11.2m)<br />

- EuroAirport Basel-Mulhouse-Freiburg (3.8m)<br />

This structure is the result <strong>of</strong> the industry's hub economics, characterised by economies<br />

<strong>of</strong> scale <strong>and</strong> network effects. In other words, only airports exceeding a critical size are<br />

able to operate a hub efficiently, <strong>and</strong> - in combination with a sizeable catchment area -<br />

can attract the needed number <strong>of</strong> airlines <strong>and</strong> connecting passengers to ensure an<br />

economically viable operation. Due to the small size <strong>of</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong> as a country, <strong>and</strong><br />

the distribution <strong>of</strong> its population, only Zurich Airport has a hub function with a<br />

significant share <strong>of</strong> transfer passengers. Our case object, which will be analysed next,<br />

is Flughafen Zürich AG as the operator <strong>of</strong> Zurich airport <strong>and</strong> an international airport<br />

management company.<br />

249


250<br />

Case Studies<br />

5.2.3 <strong>The</strong> case <strong>of</strong> Flughafen Zürich AG (Zurich Airport)<br />

Since 2000 Flughafen Zürich AG (FZ) is a publicly traded company 110 , partially<br />

owned by the state, respectively by the Canton <strong>of</strong> Zurich (33.3% <strong>of</strong> equity) <strong>and</strong> the<br />

City <strong>of</strong> Zurich (5.0%). Today FZ is a diversified company that operates Zurich Airport<br />

on behalf <strong>of</strong> the federal government. For this purpose, it has been awarded a State<br />

Concession until 2051, which entails the m<strong>and</strong>ate to provide infrastructure <strong>and</strong><br />

services in accordance with the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Swiss people, Switzerl<strong>and</strong>'s economy<br />

<strong>and</strong> tourism industry. Its compliance with this m<strong>and</strong>ate is determined by the criteria <strong>of</strong><br />

economic utility, safety <strong>and</strong> security, efficiency, quality <strong>and</strong> with regard to its<br />

environmental impact. FZ receives no subsidisation <strong>and</strong> generates annual revenues <strong>of</strong><br />

CHF 820m with 1550 employees (2009). According to its website, FZ's expertise as an<br />

airport operator is summarised through the following core competences 111<br />

- operational excellence: optimisation <strong>of</strong> operational processes <strong>and</strong> quality<br />

management<br />

- commercial competence: definition <strong>of</strong> commercial strategies <strong>and</strong> optimisation<br />

<strong>of</strong> non-aviation revenues<br />

- master planning <strong>and</strong> construction management<br />

- start-up <strong>and</strong> expansion planning <strong>and</strong> execution <strong>of</strong> airports <strong>and</strong> buildings<br />

- partnership management: with authorities, airport partners, concessionaires,<br />

customers, etc.<br />

With Zurich airport as one <strong>of</strong> Europe's best-managed airports, FZ exploits this<br />

expertise also by means <strong>of</strong> international airport engagements. <strong>The</strong> subsequent analysis<br />

therefore focuses on FZ as the operator <strong>of</strong> Zurich Airport, but occasionally draws on<br />

various experiences <strong>and</strong> cases from its international engagements, particularly FZ's<br />

involvement in a greenfield airport project in the South Indian city <strong>of</strong> Bengaluru<br />

(Bangalore).<br />

History <strong>and</strong> organisation. Until its privatisation in 2000 FZ was a single-site airport<br />

operator with no further engagements at other airports. In the past decade, however,<br />

the firm has developed into an international airport operator, developer, <strong>and</strong><br />

consultancy <strong>of</strong>fering its services on a global scale. To a limited extent, <strong>and</strong> as far as<br />

110<br />

<strong>The</strong> newly created firm was the result <strong>of</strong> merging the 'Flughafen Direktion Zürich' (FDZ), which<br />

until then belonged to the cantonal administration, <strong>and</strong> the 'Flughafen Immobilien Gesellschaft' (FIG),<br />

which took care <strong>of</strong> the airport infrastructure.<br />

111<br />

See also 'Our Expertise'. Retrieved April 18, 2010, from Zurich Airport's corporate website:<br />

http://www.zurich-airport.com/desktopdefault.aspx/tabid-435/.


Case Studies<br />

required, FZ also holds minority stakes at the airports, where it is active. Its dual<br />

orientation towards maintaining its high st<strong>and</strong>ards at the homebase in Zurich <strong>and</strong> to<br />

exp<strong>and</strong> in its international activities is reflected in FZ's vision (Flughafen Zürich AG,<br />

2009):<br />

We connect Switzerl<strong>and</strong> to the world;<br />

we welcome our guests around the clock;<br />

we develop projects in Switzerl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> abroad;<br />

<strong>and</strong> we distinguish ourselves through “Swissness”.<br />

Like most major airports, FZ has a functional organisation (cf. Figure 5-6). Its<br />

operational knowledge is embedded in the functional units, while the project knowhow<br />

for international activities is concentrated in its finance division. Whenever<br />

operational expertise <strong>and</strong> best practice advice is needed in international activities, the<br />

latter is able to draw on the relevant experts across the firm.<br />

Operations<br />

Marketing &<br />

Real Estate<br />

Board <strong>of</strong> Directors<br />

CEO<br />

Figure 5-6: Functional organisation <strong>of</strong> Flughafen Zürich AG<br />

Finance Services<br />

Strategic orientation & geographical presence. In FZ's portfolio <strong>of</strong> managed<br />

airports, Zurich airport is <strong>and</strong> will remain the core asset due to its size <strong>and</strong> strategic<br />

importance for the firm. Zurich airport is not only the homebase to which FZ is<br />

committed through its concession, its shareholders <strong>and</strong> through its tradition, it<br />

represents also FZ's showcase operation, from which it draws its credibility <strong>and</strong><br />

reputation for its international activities, as well as the required knowledge for best<br />

practice transfers to foreign projects. Geographically FZ's international activities focus<br />

on Latin <strong>and</strong> Central America, as well as Asia, where it already has invested in<br />

airports. In 2008, the firm widened its strategic focus also to Central <strong>and</strong> Eastern<br />

Europe where it is actively seeking airport engagements. International engagements as<br />

airport operator are chosen on the basis <strong>of</strong> their size <strong>and</strong> development potential, i.e. FZ<br />

focuses on airports where it is able to transfer best practice knowledge with the highest<br />

leverage. Consequently, it concentrates on the development <strong>and</strong> operation <strong>of</strong> mediumsized<br />

airports mostly in emerging markets, which are in high need for the upgrading<br />

251


252<br />

Case Studies<br />

<strong>and</strong> development <strong>of</strong> aviation infrastructure, or in environments where the commercial<br />

potential <strong>of</strong> airports is not yet exploited. FZ's international airport portfolio involved<br />

eleven airports in six countries in 2009, as illustrated in Figure 5-7.<br />

Mexico<br />

Honduras<br />

(4 airports)<br />

Colombia<br />

Bogota<br />

Peru<br />

La Serena<br />

Chile<br />

Puerto Montt<br />

Curacao, Curacao<br />

Venezuela,<br />

Isla Margarita<br />

Brazil<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong>,<br />

Zurich<br />

Eastern<br />

Europe<br />

Figure 5-7: International engagements <strong>of</strong> Flughafen Zürich AG (2010) 112<br />

India<br />

Bangalore<br />

Vietnam<br />

airport operations<br />

strategic focus areas<br />

In its strategy-finding process FZ identified four primary business models with regard<br />

to international activities (cf. Figure 5-8): (1) consultancies with knowhow <strong>and</strong> a shortterm<br />

orientation confined to their m<strong>and</strong>ate; (2) operators, who possess the knowhow<br />

<strong>and</strong> have a long-term orientation to the airports they manage; (3) developers, who are<br />

primarily interested in airport construction <strong>and</strong> start-up; <strong>and</strong> (4) investors with a longterm<br />

orientation <strong>and</strong> financial means, but lacking operational knowhow.<br />

112 Company information.


Case Studies<br />

Knowhow<br />

Factor endowment<br />

Financial funds<br />

Orientation<br />

short-term long-term<br />

(1) Consultant (2) Operator<br />

(3) Developer (4) Investor<br />

Figure 5-8: Primary business models in international airport activities 113<br />

Among these strategic choices FZ sets its focus primarily on the operator-role, taking<br />

responsibility for airports through management <strong>and</strong> operation agreements. As its<br />

former Chief Development Officer specifies: “we engage ourselves for the long-term,<br />

with our main contribution being our knowhow <strong>and</strong> not capital” (interview N°24: 1).<br />

FZ sees its core competency in the operation <strong>and</strong> management <strong>of</strong> complex airport<br />

systems sized between 5-25m passengers, where the knowhow from its Zurich<br />

operation can be best employed. In its engagements it always cooperates with a<br />

strongly embedded local majority partner, helping it to overcome its liabilities <strong>of</strong><br />

foreignness. Other project-related financial obligations <strong>and</strong> equity participation<br />

requirements are covered by selected strategic partners, <strong>of</strong>ten with a venture capital<br />

background. FZ also <strong>of</strong>fers consulting services 114 , but regards them as a means<br />

towards project acquisition.<br />

Corporate philosophy. In its annual report 2009 (Flughafen Zürich AG, 2010) FZ<br />

states about its business approach:<br />

When formulating <strong>and</strong> implementing its strategy, the operator <strong>of</strong> Zurich Airport<br />

gives due consideration to the aspects <strong>of</strong> cost-efficiency, environment <strong>and</strong> social<br />

responsibility in its decision-making. In this way it aims to increase the company's<br />

competitiveness <strong>and</strong> credibility <strong>and</strong> add to its value on a sustainable basis.<br />

113 Cf. interview N°24.<br />

114<br />

FZ's engagement in Colombia, for example, comprises mainly consulting services, with the<br />

prospect <strong>of</strong> more far-reaching involvements in the future.<br />

253


254<br />

Case Studies<br />

Due to the relevance <strong>of</strong> airports for their surrounding economic system <strong>and</strong> their<br />

impacts on the local environment, FZ sees itself as an intermediary <strong>and</strong> ambassador to<br />

the region. Zurich airport, for example is positioned as being the Gateway to the Alps.<br />

Similarly, its greenfield operation in India, Bengaluru International Airport markets<br />

itself <strong>and</strong> the region as 'Gateway to South India'. <strong>The</strong> strength <strong>of</strong> this philosophy lies in<br />

the tying together <strong>of</strong> various local interest groups to mutually benefit from each other,<br />

e.g. by closely coordinating the airport's activities with local tourism organisations <strong>and</strong><br />

economic development agencies to promote the region surrounding the airport, its<br />

business centres <strong>and</strong> touristic attractions. In addition, FZ considers itself as a reliable<br />

factor for the growth <strong>of</strong> the local economy. In its mission statement FZ consequently<br />

states (excerpt):<br />

We perceive it as our duty to strengthen Switzerl<strong>and</strong> as a business centre, as a<br />

country with a rich tradition <strong>of</strong> culture, know-how <strong>and</strong> sport, <strong>and</strong> as an attractive<br />

tourist destination, by operating a well-developed <strong>and</strong> efficient gateway to the<br />

world. …<br />

We make the best possible use <strong>of</strong> our know-how in Switzerl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> abroad by<br />

developing <strong>and</strong> implementing projects aimed at enhancing economic performance<br />

<strong>and</strong> efficiency.<br />

We distinguish ourselves from our competitors by consistently implementing<br />

positive Swiss values – i.e. “Swissness”.<br />

Through FZ's consistent quality <strong>and</strong> service orientation <strong>and</strong> an established feedback<br />

culture (also with its service partners) towards continuous improvement, Zurich airport<br />

consistently ranks among the top-rated airports <strong>of</strong> Europe.<br />

5.2.4 Flughafen Zürich AG's location-fixity<br />

FZ's location-fixity is grounded in the l<strong>and</strong> it has been allocated for operation, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

resulting sunk-cost from investments in the airport's assets. In addition, the operator <strong>of</strong><br />

an airport takes on concession-related obligations, which it has to comply to until its<br />

concession expires. In the case <strong>of</strong> Zurich airport, FZ maintains <strong>and</strong> further develops<br />

800 hectares <strong>of</strong> l<strong>and</strong>, which comprise assets in the value <strong>of</strong> 3.1bn Swiss Francs (2009).<br />

In Table 5-4 the dimensions <strong>of</strong> FZ's location dependence are further detailed.


Case Studies<br />

Characteristic Applicable<br />

for FZ<br />

Upstream<br />

Natural<br />

Resource<br />

Dependence<br />

Upstream<br />

Tangible<br />

Asset<br />

Dependence<br />

Downstream<br />

Dependence<br />

on Market<br />

Proximity<br />

Ownership<br />

Dependence<br />

on Owners'<br />

Utility<br />

Function<br />

Comment<br />

� Due to the spatial <strong>and</strong> topographical requirements <strong>of</strong> airports,<br />

including the need for large coherent pieces <strong>of</strong> undeveloped l<strong>and</strong> to<br />

accommodate an airport <strong>and</strong> a runway system, FZ's dependence on<br />

a natural resource can be affirmed. Once the airport is built <strong>and</strong> the<br />

economic development around the airport perimeter sets in, its<br />

location becomes practically unalterable.<br />

� Airports' highly specific infrastructure usually is <strong>of</strong> little value<br />

outside its intended use, their assets have long amortisation periods,<br />

averaging 25-30 years for runways <strong>and</strong> 30 years for terminal<br />

buildings. Combined with related sunk costs for such lumpy<br />

investments this creates significant dependence on tangible assets.<br />

� <strong>The</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> their product, respectively <strong>of</strong> their provided services<br />

makes airports dependent on their catchment area, i.e. the radius<br />

within which people choose a specific airport as a starting or ending<br />

point <strong>of</strong> a journey. It is therefore essential for the economic viability<br />

<strong>of</strong> an airport that it is located close to a sufficient number <strong>of</strong> airport<br />

users, depending on its size <strong>and</strong> business model. Thus FZ, in all <strong>of</strong><br />

its geographically diverse airport operations, depends on the<br />

proximity to its market in the form <strong>of</strong> local passengers.<br />

� Although its equity is predominantly freely floated, 38.3% <strong>of</strong> FZ<br />

belong to public shareholders, i.e. the Canton <strong>of</strong> Zurich <strong>and</strong> the City<br />

<strong>of</strong> Zurich. Because airport operations imply noise <strong>and</strong> air emissions,<br />

conflicts <strong>of</strong> interest between the public shareholder <strong>and</strong> the airport's<br />

management naturally may arise.<br />

� fully applicable / ~ weakly applicable / � not applicable<br />

In the case <strong>of</strong> FZ, which is closely located to the city centre <strong>of</strong><br />

Zurich <strong>and</strong> embedded in a densely populated web <strong>of</strong> surrounding<br />

communities, stakeholder tensions related to aircraft noise exist.<br />

Consequently, the Canton <strong>of</strong> Zurich as the airport's largest<br />

shareholders <strong>and</strong> representative <strong>of</strong> the people <strong>of</strong> Zurich attempts to<br />

mitigate these tensions by seeking political solutions. During the<br />

past decade it experienced the thereto related difficulties to balance<br />

between the economic interests <strong>of</strong> Zurich as a business location, the<br />

interests <strong>of</strong> the noise-affected inhabitants, <strong>and</strong> the interests <strong>of</strong> FZ as<br />

a private company.<br />

Table 5-4: <strong>Location</strong> dependence <strong>of</strong> Flughafen Zürich AG by construct characteristics<br />

To sum up, FZ can be considered as location-dependent on all relevant construct<br />

characteristics. How this dependence affects its institutional exposure, <strong>and</strong> how FZ is<br />

able to reduce its local exposure will be further elaborated in the subsequent sections.<br />

255


256<br />

Case Studies<br />

5.2.5 Flughafen Zürich AG's environment - institutional exposure<br />

Commercial airports are public utilities which serve the economic development <strong>of</strong> a<br />

region, satisfy the local population's needs for mobility, but also contribute to noise<br />

<strong>and</strong> air emissions, <strong>and</strong> to other environmental impacts on their surroundings.<br />

Moreover, the visibility <strong>of</strong> airport activities adds a political dimension to their<br />

business. <strong>The</strong> resulting dilemma is exemplified by Zurich airport's positive economic<br />

impact on the region, making the latter attractive to new incomers, while creating an<br />

increasing dissonance with its externality-affected local stakeholders, who oppose its<br />

further growth. <strong>The</strong>se tensions between economic, environmental <strong>and</strong> social<br />

dimensions <strong>of</strong> an airport's activities are illustrated in Figure 5-9. Essentially, a healthy<br />

balance between the three dimensions is imperative to the airport's organisational<br />

legitimacy, <strong>and</strong> influences also the institutional exposure towards the individual<br />

stakeholders.<br />

Environment<br />

(air <strong>and</strong> noise<br />

emission potential)<br />

Economy<br />

(economic utility & market<br />

potential Zurich airport)<br />

Sustainable civil aviation<br />

sector development<br />

in the Zurich region<br />

(ecological damage ≤<br />

economic <strong>and</strong> societal utility)<br />

societal utility ≥<br />

ecological damage<br />

Figure 5-9: Field <strong>of</strong> tension between Zurich airport <strong>and</strong> its environment 115<br />

Society<br />

(potential <strong>of</strong> social contacts)<br />

Consequently, the 'trouble-potential' which is related to Zurich airport's interlinkage<br />

with its environment, to the current political dynamics, <strong>and</strong> the local dependence is<br />

substantial (cf. interview N°23: 7). In the subsequent passages, we elaborate in more<br />

detail FZ's institutional exposure towards its individual stakeholder groups.<br />

<strong>Local</strong> community: exposure towards voting population <strong>and</strong> noise affected<br />

population. To some extent airports are the victims <strong>of</strong> their own success 116 . While<br />

115<br />

Wittmer, Fröhlich, Weinert, & Axhausen, 2008: 12.<br />

116<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the core problems <strong>of</strong> the relations between Zurich airport <strong>and</strong> its surrounding communities<br />

lies in the increased popularity <strong>of</strong> the airport region: On one h<strong>and</strong>, the size <strong>of</strong> noise-affected areas<br />

within the defined immission threshold shrank by two thirds within the past two decades, due to<br />

technologically advanced aircraft. At the same time, the population <strong>of</strong> the airport-surrounding


Case Studies<br />

they increase the economic attractiveness <strong>of</strong> the region in which they are located, they<br />

equally - thereto related - are resented by the local population, due to their emissions.<br />

Consequently,<br />

the relationship between Flughafen Zürich AG <strong>and</strong> the general public is marked by<br />

numerous contradictions. On one h<strong>and</strong>, people expect a reliable, high-quality<br />

service provider which takes the society’s continuously increasing dem<strong>and</strong> for<br />

mobility into consideration. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, Flughafen Zürich AG is confronted<br />

by dem<strong>and</strong>s related to airport-related noise from the population groups that want<br />

the number <strong>of</strong> flight movements – counter to global trends – kept at current levels<br />

or even reduced. (Flughafen Zürich AG, 2008: 17)<br />

For the past three decades FZ faces an unresolved conflict with noise-affected<br />

municipalities who benefit from airport-related popularity-increases <strong>and</strong> who need to<br />

argue in the interests <strong>of</strong> their inhabitants to limit noise emissions. As a result,FZ finds<br />

itself in a position <strong>of</strong> very limited flexibility. Many stakeholders oppose its existing<br />

approach <strong>and</strong> departure routes from a 'not-in-my-backyard' perspective. Equally every<br />

change to the existing system, particularly any capacity-enhancing measures to fulfil<br />

FZ's public m<strong>and</strong>ate in providing dem<strong>and</strong>-sufficing infrastructure, meets resistance.<br />

<strong>The</strong> airport's planning processes are thus prolonged <strong>and</strong> involve higher risks <strong>and</strong><br />

uncertainty. Many intended changes run through a long legal appeals process, resulting<br />

in time-inefficiencies <strong>and</strong> procedural costs.<br />

Civilian interest groups: exposure towards noise-related <strong>and</strong> environmental<br />

groups. Concerned with issues <strong>of</strong> quality <strong>of</strong> life <strong>and</strong> real estate resale values, a number<br />

<strong>of</strong> noise-centred associations actively promote their members' interests. <strong>The</strong> most<br />

prominent <strong>of</strong> them are the Verein Flugschneise Süd Nein, Zürich Nord gegen<br />

Fluglärm, IG Nord, Bürgerprotest Fluglärm Ost, <strong>and</strong> the Schutzverb<strong>and</strong> der<br />

Bevölkerung um den Flughafen Zürich (SBFZ). Many <strong>of</strong> these interest groups are<br />

actively involved in political processes, for example through the launch <strong>of</strong> popular<br />

initiatives or the filing <strong>of</strong> petitions. Moreover, with regard to concrete business<br />

development activities or changes in Zurich airport's aeronautical processes, they also<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten choose legal actions, which may involve several time-consuming juridical levels.<br />

communities has increased by 20-85%, compared to the cantonal average <strong>of</strong> 15% (Müller-Jentsch,<br />

2009). This is also reflected by the intensity <strong>of</strong> construction activities: between 2003 <strong>and</strong> 2008 the<br />

areas, which the regional structure plan designates as exceeding the immission limits for noise<br />

exposure, have seen a growth <strong>of</strong> 10.8% in the overall number <strong>of</strong> apartments - a growth-rate more than<br />

double the cantonal average <strong>of</strong> 4.8% in the same period (Fuhrer, 2009).<br />

257


258<br />

Case Studies<br />

Because FZ is already a best practice airport with regard to sustainability <strong>and</strong><br />

environmental protection, it faces barely any exposure from environmental groups.<br />

Customers: exposure to dominant airline alliances <strong>and</strong> business cycle<br />

dependence. Airports serve two types <strong>of</strong> customers, airlines <strong>and</strong> passengers. From the<br />

side <strong>of</strong> the airlines, institutional exposure has grown over the past two decades<br />

particularly with the formation <strong>of</strong> airline alliances, which strengthen their members'<br />

negotiation power. Importantly, it has also risen due to the increasing influence <strong>of</strong> low<br />

cost carriers. At Zurich airport its single biggest airline customer - its hub carrier Swiss<br />

International Airlines - has a market share <strong>of</strong> 59% (2009), while the market share <strong>of</strong><br />

the world's biggest airline alliance Star Alliance adds up to 72% <strong>of</strong> all transported<br />

passengers. This dominant position allows the alliance members to negotiate hubspecific<br />

investments, resulting in institutional exposure for the airport due to the<br />

related sunk costs <strong>and</strong> few guarantees to ensure credible commitments 117 from the<br />

airlines. Moreover, airlines' volatility <strong>and</strong> sensitivity to business cycles regularly pose<br />

challenges to airports, which are characterised by high fixed costs in their operation. In<br />

this respect, Airports Council International (ACI) (2009: 1.7.1c), an international<br />

industry association, points out:<br />

Airports are significantly exposed to the airline industry which is very susceptible to<br />

external circumstances forcing it frequently to revisit business models <strong>and</strong><br />

strategies which immediately affect airports. … Airport infrastructure development<br />

is a long term undertaking which must not be disrupted by short term airline<br />

industry volatility.<br />

From the passengers' side, institutional exposure mainly stems from the aviation<br />

industry's cyclicality, i.e. the decrease <strong>of</strong> local dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> increased pricesensitivity<br />

118 in times <strong>of</strong> economic downturn.<br />

Suppliers: no relevant exposure to strategic suppliers. Zurich airport has few<br />

strategic suppliers, from which it derives institutional exposure. Most <strong>of</strong> its strategic<br />

relations are with its service partners, on which the smooth airport operation crucially<br />

depends (see next paragraph).<br />

117 On the other h<strong>and</strong>, airlines face a hold-up risk from the airport, since they are equally dependent on<br />

the functioning <strong>of</strong> airport infrastructure for smooth <strong>and</strong> cost-efficient performance. In addition, airlines<br />

face hold-up risks in non-regulated airport charges, due to the natural monopoly situation <strong>of</strong> airports.<br />

118<br />

Price-sensitivity is felt most significantly by the airlines, but also by the airport's commercial<br />

partners due to passengers' lower willingness to spend while travelling.


Case Studies<br />

Service partners: hold-up situations in case <strong>of</strong> disruptions with service partners,<br />

i.e. air traffic control, ground h<strong>and</strong>ling companies, caterers, aircraft refuellers,<br />

security services <strong>and</strong> customs. Airports are intricate systems <strong>of</strong> well attuned service<br />

partners. Depending on the airport operator's business model <strong>and</strong> national regulations,<br />

the number <strong>of</strong> such partners varies. FZ depends on the well-functioning <strong>of</strong> the abovelisted<br />

service partners. Although it has issued more than one concession for the<br />

coverage <strong>of</strong> ground h<strong>and</strong>ling <strong>and</strong> catering, with service level agreements in place,<br />

disruptions <strong>of</strong> a partner would lead to operational inconveniences, additional costs <strong>and</strong><br />

might result in negative reputational spillovers.<br />

Employees: labour issues, strikes. As recent examples <strong>of</strong> strikes have shown in Los<br />

Angeles (airport workers, 2008), at various airports in Italy (air traffic controllers,<br />

2008), Frankfurt (ground staff, 2009), or at London's BAA-operated airports (ground<br />

staff, 2007), airports are exposed to hold-up situations from labour issues, be it their<br />

own employees or through the employees <strong>of</strong> their service partners. Labour issues in<br />

the form <strong>of</strong> strikes or non-cooperation may lead to system disruptions, which in their<br />

worst case may take the airport weeks to recover from. With view at Zurich airport, a<br />

cooperative firm culture <strong>and</strong> functioning mediation processes between FZ's<br />

management <strong>and</strong> its employees have helped to constructively resolve any issue in the<br />

airport's history. With regard to its social partnership, FZ states in its annual report<br />

2009 (2010: 19):<br />

In all matters concerning Flughafen Zürich AG's operations, both the employer <strong>and</strong><br />

the staff representation council (PeV) work closely together. <strong>The</strong> participation <strong>of</strong><br />

the staff representation council has a direct effect on those who work for Flughafen<br />

Zürich AG <strong>and</strong> it is a key feature in how the employer/employee relationship works.<br />

Both the Management Board <strong>and</strong> line managers acknowledge the importance <strong>of</strong> the<br />

staff representatives' work to the social partnership.<br />

In addition, the Swiss culture has developed effective systems to h<strong>and</strong>le firmemployee<br />

disagreements, which rarely result in strike situations. Thus, also service<br />

partners' risk <strong>of</strong> escalating labour issues is small. This characteristic Swiss mediation<br />

capability has so far helped FZ to avoid labour issues also in its international airport<br />

activities.<br />

Shareholder: exposure due to conflicting priorities <strong>of</strong> public shareholders. <strong>The</strong><br />

objectives, that the Canton <strong>of</strong> Zurich specifies as FZ's major shareholder aim to ensure<br />

a balance between transportation-related, macro-economic, as well as environmental<br />

interests. <strong>The</strong>refore, the Canton formulates its expectations towards FZ through its<br />

259


260<br />

Case Studies<br />

strategic investment controlling, considering the following dimensions: (1) mobilityrelated<br />

<strong>and</strong> economic relevance <strong>of</strong> the airport; (2) environmental protection; (3)<br />

business management <strong>and</strong> governance; <strong>and</strong> (4) stakeholder management (Amt für<br />

Verkehr, 2009). In its strategy-controlling report on FZ, the Canton states, that “by<br />

means <strong>of</strong> influence through the State [on the airport operator] - which is essential in<br />

airport politics - the population can be given account for the Canton's investment, the<br />

pursued goals, <strong>and</strong> the compliance therewith” (ibid: 4). With regard to FZ's<br />

international activities, the Canton further specifies (ibid: 6):<br />

Principally the Canton <strong>of</strong> Zurich expects that … Flughafen Zürich AG invests in<br />

national or international airport projects only under the condition that the thus<br />

bound human <strong>and</strong> financial resources are proportionate to their value created for<br />

Zurich airport, <strong>and</strong> that the risk <strong>of</strong> legal claims against the Canton <strong>of</strong> Zurich as a<br />

shareholder can be precluded with high certainty.<br />

Concludingly, FZ has the opportunity to develop its international activities according<br />

to economic principles <strong>and</strong> diligent risk management, as long as it is able to comply<br />

with the performance expectations in the management <strong>of</strong> Zurich airport. With regard<br />

to the development <strong>of</strong> Zurich airport as an infrastructure, however, the political<br />

realities limit FZ in capacity expansions, thus forcing it to become more efficient<br />

within the bounds <strong>of</strong> the existing capacity - which is also reflected in the Canton's<br />

performance targets.<br />

Government, regulator, politics: exposure due to the industry's polarisation <strong>of</strong><br />

the local electorate <strong>and</strong> its public utility function. Due to the long-term orientation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the airport industry, which faces long break-even periods, high risks <strong>and</strong> needs<br />

substantial policy <strong>and</strong> financial support, regulatory regimes equally need to take a<br />

long-term perspective, considering both current <strong>and</strong> future beneficiaries <strong>of</strong> the airport<br />

assets. However, in the face <strong>of</strong> limited information <strong>and</strong> uncertain market conditions,<br />

reinforced by political pressures arising from airports' high visibility <strong>and</strong> polarisation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the electorate, regulators potentially make shorter-term decisions, which increase<br />

the exposure <strong>of</strong> airport operators in a number <strong>of</strong> ways. Particularly the fact that<br />

airports have to provide sufficient infrastructure through lumpy investments 119 in<br />

anticipation <strong>of</strong> future growth, makes them vulnerable to the public stakeholders'<br />

reneging on contracts. In addition, if the perceived regulatory risks are high for airport<br />

119<br />

Lumpy investments are characterised by investment spikes, with little or no investment activity<br />

between the spikes (cf. Nilsen, Raknerud, Rybalka, & Skjerpen, 2005).


Case Studies<br />

operators, their incentives to proactively invest in additional capacity in a timely<br />

manner are low, which exposes them to criticisms <strong>of</strong> underinvestment.<br />

In the case <strong>of</strong> FZ, one <strong>of</strong> the main obstacles to its business development in Zurich<br />

stems from its political exposure. According to article one <strong>of</strong> the cantonal airport law<br />

("Flughafengesetz", 1999), the Canton supports Zurich airport in all aspects affecting<br />

its economic <strong>and</strong> transportation-economic interests. It thereby considers the protection<br />

<strong>of</strong> the population from adverse <strong>and</strong> undesirable impacts <strong>of</strong> the airport operation. In the<br />

past three decades the political situation has evolved in a way which makes solutionfinding<br />

very complex <strong>and</strong> time-consuming, due to the afore-described field <strong>of</strong> tension<br />

between the economy, society <strong>and</strong> the environment (cf. Figure 5-9). Thus, even though<br />

FZ is willing to invest in additional capacity to fulfil its concession m<strong>and</strong>ate,<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong>ten is slowed down or prevented through procedural, legalistic<br />

loops.<br />

In its international engagements, its regulatory <strong>and</strong> political exposure is <strong>of</strong>ten less<br />

related to (noise) emissions, but to the economic impact <strong>of</strong> airports <strong>and</strong> the question <strong>of</strong><br />

fair rates <strong>of</strong> return. India, for example is currently developing a new regulatory regime<br />

with uncertain impacts on the recently privatised airports. In a white paper, the newly<br />

established 'Airports Economic Regulatory Authority' (AERA) states: “<strong>The</strong> process <strong>of</strong><br />

regulation, could itself significantly protect investors from key aspects <strong>of</strong> risk.<br />

Notably, the periodic review <strong>of</strong> airport <strong>and</strong> aeronautical services tariffs provides<br />

mechanisms for risk to be shared between an airport <strong>and</strong> its users – subject to<br />

safeguards to protect users” (AERA, 2009: 40). This statement proves correct in a<br />

regime, which has firmly established processes <strong>and</strong> in which proven past stability<br />

provides certainty to the investors also in the future. In institutional environments with<br />

a less stable history, the protection <strong>of</strong> users might lead to a politically motivated<br />

challenging <strong>of</strong> investors' assumptions in determining an airport's fair rate <strong>of</strong> return,<br />

potentially putting their business case at risk. Thus, the international industry<br />

association Airports Council International (ACI, 2009: 1.7.1c) recommends:<br />

When calculating a reasonable rate <strong>of</strong> return, the various <strong>and</strong> potentially<br />

significant degrees <strong>of</strong> risk airports are exposed to must be taken into account. …<br />

<strong>The</strong> airports’ ability to react to negative developments can be limited as airport<br />

infrastructure cannot simply be decommissioned.<br />

261


262<br />

Case Studies<br />

5.2.6 Flughafen Zürich AG's embedding capabilities<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the biggest challenges in an airport's legitimisation process lies in the finding<br />

<strong>of</strong> the right balance between its own economic interests <strong>and</strong> its stakeholders' social<br />

interests under consideration <strong>of</strong> the political circumstances (cf. interview N°13). This<br />

task revolves around delicate issues, most notably the airport's externalities affecting<br />

the local community's quality <strong>of</strong> life. If the pendulum swings too far towards economic<br />

interests, resulting in a neglect <strong>of</strong> social issues, the whole system between airport,<br />

society, environment <strong>and</strong> politics becomes unstable, <strong>and</strong> further business development<br />

options may become uncertain (cf. interview N°23: 1). Thus, from its history at Zurich<br />

airport, FZ knows that the continuous nurturing <strong>of</strong> stakeholder relationships is a<br />

critical success factor. Its experiences with a highly complex environment <strong>and</strong> very<br />

limited flexibility for further development have enabled it to develop an alertness to<br />

sense which kind <strong>of</strong> cooperation mode with the various stakeholders will be fruitful - a<br />

treat which is also valuable in its international activities.<br />

Capabilities towards structural local embedding. When FZ emerged as a privatised<br />

company in 2000, it coined the company motto “to operate the airport together with<br />

the community”, which pointedly reflects the airport's self-conception. <strong>The</strong> operation<br />

<strong>of</strong> Zurich airport can never be an end in itself, but receives its 'licence to operate' by<br />

fulfilling its role in serving the society, the economy <strong>and</strong> the state in the wider sense<br />

(cf. interview N° 23: 2). In the subsequent sections we will examine along the<br />

parameters <strong>of</strong> the research framework, in which ways FZ is able to strengthen its<br />

structural embeddedness <strong>and</strong> its stakeholder legitimisation.<br />

(a) value share remaining in region. Beyond its function as provider <strong>of</strong> infrastructure,<br />

an airport represents an integral part <strong>of</strong> a business location. Moreover, through its<br />

activities it promotes the creation <strong>and</strong> exploitation <strong>of</strong> a region's economic growth<br />

potential. Consequently, the direct value added <strong>of</strong> the airport operator itself is<br />

subordinate to the economic effects <strong>of</strong> the airport as an overall system. From a bird's<br />

eye perspective, an airport creates value in its local environment on various levels. In<br />

order to assess its economic relevance ACI <strong>and</strong> York Consulting (2000) recommend to<br />

divide its impact in direct <strong>and</strong> indirect effects. <strong>The</strong> direct effects measure its value<br />

added (equalling sales minus inputs) <strong>and</strong> the employment effects on its premises<br />

through activities <strong>of</strong> other firms, which are located there. In contrast, indirect effects<br />

measure the inputs <strong>of</strong> firms outside the airport, which contribute to the direct value<br />

added. Table 5-5 provides an overview on Zurich airport's direct <strong>and</strong> indirect value<br />

added effects for the year 2004, plus from a broader economic perspective on the


Case Studies<br />

somewhat less reliably assessable multiplication effects. <strong>The</strong> latter include induced<br />

effects 120 <strong>and</strong> catalytic effects 121 , which relate to effects from the region's improved<br />

connectivity to the world (Infras, 2006).<br />

Economic effects (CHF million)<br />

direct effect 3'081<br />

indirect effect 841<br />

sum <strong>of</strong> direct <strong>and</strong> indirect effect (narrowly defined economic benefit) 3'922<br />

induced effect 5'740<br />

catalytic effect (passenger-related) 4'118<br />

sum <strong>of</strong> induced <strong>and</strong> catalytic effect (widely defined economic benefit) 9'858<br />

overall effect 13'780<br />

Table 5-5: Overall value added <strong>of</strong> Zurich airport (2004) 122<br />

Caused by Switzerl<strong>and</strong>'s economic growth <strong>and</strong> related growth in annual passenger<br />

volumes, in 2009 Zurich airport's overall employment throughout the service chain<br />

grew to 21'000 full time equivalents, which makes it one <strong>of</strong> the country's most<br />

important employers. Furthermore, considering its multiplication effects, in 2009 more<br />

than 100'000 people earned their livelihoods related to the airport. Its direct <strong>and</strong><br />

indirect value added amounted to CHF 20bn (airport- / airline- / retail plus F&B<br />

related effects) (Flughafen Zürich AG, 2010).<br />

Narrowing the perspective on value contribution to the airport operator itself, FZ<br />

creates value in the greater Zurich region through<br />

- stable annual tax payments, amounting to CHF 26m in 2008123;<br />

- economic impulses through investments in major real estate projects, such as<br />

the fifth expansion phase (1999-2004, with an investment volume <strong>of</strong> CHF<br />

2.1bn), Zurich 2010 (2008-2011, with an investment volume: CHF 0.43bn), or<br />

120<br />

I.e. the value added <strong>and</strong> employment effects from the additional purchasing power, which results<br />

from the jobs created through the airport's activity.<br />

121<br />

I.e. the spending <strong>of</strong> foreign passengers who visit Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> productivity effects respectively<br />

additional sales <strong>of</strong> firms which benefit from the airport's infrastructure.<br />

122<br />

Infras, 2006.<br />

123<br />

In 2009, FZ paid CHF 48.4m in income taxes, which included one-<strong>of</strong>f effects from its divestment<br />

<strong>of</strong> a 12% stake in Bangalore International Airport Ltd. (BIAL).<br />

263


264<br />

Case Studies<br />

the planned development <strong>of</strong> an airport city through its 'Circle' project (with an<br />

estimated overall investment volume <strong>of</strong> CHF 1bn); <strong>and</strong><br />

- annual expenditures for sound insulation measures/noise compensation <strong>of</strong> CHF<br />

6.8m, to which FZ is obliged by law <strong>and</strong> which it finances from its noise fund<br />

(see also next paragraph).<br />

With the objective to compensate particularly emission-affected citizens for their<br />

reduction in quality <strong>of</strong> life, FZ has established a noise fund, which is financed through<br />

special noise charges based on the principle <strong>of</strong> “user pays”. FZ describes in its annual<br />

report (Flughafen Zürich AG, 2010: 16):<br />

Our sound insulation concept is a key measure for abating aircraft noise, second in<br />

importance only to the use <strong>of</strong> quieter engines <strong>and</strong> the improvement <strong>of</strong>, <strong>and</strong><br />

adherence to, operating instructions. Sound-insulating windows provide local<br />

residents with passive protection against the intrusive <strong>and</strong> harmful effects <strong>of</strong><br />

aircraft noise. Owners <strong>of</strong> properties exposed to noise <strong>and</strong> which are located in a<br />

clearly defined area within the airport (“sound insulation perimeter”) have certain<br />

entitlements in respect <strong>of</strong> sound-insulating windows. Property owners who have<br />

already taken the initiative <strong>of</strong> fitting sound-insulating windows will over the coming<br />

years be reimbursed for their investment by Flughafen Zürich AG.<br />

Moreover, FZ compensates property owners whose properties have sustained losses in<br />

value because <strong>of</strong> aircraft noise, if the immission levels as laid down by the Federal<br />

Noise Abatement Ordinance are exceeded, <strong>and</strong> if the owner could not have anticipated<br />

the aircraft noise when the property was purchased. Thus, FZ derives part <strong>of</strong> its local<br />

legitimisation through its continued construction activities at the airport, the stable tax<br />

income it creates to the surrounding communities, its noise relief provisions, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

further economic impulses the airport brings to the regions through its existence.<br />

Because in different institutional <strong>and</strong> cultural environments different legitimisation<br />

activities are expected, FZ's engagements in international airport management entail<br />

different ways <strong>of</strong> creating value in the region. In its airport operation in Bangalore for<br />

example, its legitimacy is furthered by employment <strong>of</strong> less qualified villagers from the<br />

airport's neighbouring communities, by supporting underprivileged local families, or<br />

through local forestation projects to compensate for the environmental impacts <strong>of</strong> the<br />

airport (cf. interview N°15). <strong>The</strong>se measures are part <strong>of</strong> the operator's corporate social<br />

responsibility programme, leading to an increased local living st<strong>and</strong>ard <strong>and</strong> to the<br />

accumulation <strong>of</strong> local goodwill stocks.


Case Studies<br />

(b) mutual lock-in between the firm <strong>and</strong> its major stakeholders. As has been outlined<br />

before, Flughafen Zürich AG is a privatised company with major public equity<br />

participation. Thus, FZ maintains a dual relationship with the Canton <strong>of</strong> Zurich, with<br />

the latter being both, a source <strong>of</strong> tension <strong>and</strong> a source <strong>of</strong> stability. On one side, their<br />

interactions have a legalistic, regulatory, <strong>and</strong> political character, <strong>and</strong> on the other side<br />

the Canton safeguards its interests through its role as FZ's biggest shareholder. In this<br />

role as an owner, the Canton becomes involved in the firm's strategic decision-making<br />

<strong>and</strong> takes on responsibility for the firm's governance, which incidentally increases FZ's<br />

organisational legitimacy. In addition, the shareholding represents an obligation to the<br />

Canton to duly act towards ensuring FZ's going concern, which means that it needs to<br />

balance those interests against political claims in respect <strong>of</strong> airport emissions <strong>and</strong><br />

growth. Consequently, despite irresolvable conflicts related to its activities, FZ is<br />

granted a basic legitimacy which is undisputed among its various stakeholders. <strong>The</strong><br />

Canton's equity involvement serves as a kind <strong>of</strong> guarantor to the conditions needed for<br />

future development, albeit within the bounds <strong>of</strong> social <strong>and</strong> environmental<br />

compatibility.<br />

Further illustration <strong>of</strong> mutual lock-in is provided by the affiliation <strong>of</strong> eight<br />

municipalities in the Glatt valley close to Zurich airport, with the objective to create a<br />

joint economic region promoted as GLOW area. Those communities have not only<br />

accepted that the airport <strong>and</strong> the surrounding environment are mutually dependent, but<br />

have taken steps to further exploit the resulting economic potential. In order to do so,<br />

<strong>and</strong> although the region objects to the airport's emissions under the aspect <strong>of</strong> quality <strong>of</strong><br />

life, the involved public administrations have decided to constructively cooperate with<br />

the airport. In their efforts to foster community-spanning developments, they describe<br />

GLOW as one <strong>of</strong> the most dynamic areas <strong>of</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> “the focal point between<br />

the city <strong>of</strong> Zurich <strong>and</strong> Zurich Airport” 124 . In addition, the region is being marketed as<br />

the Airport Region Zurich. <strong>The</strong> related goodwill towards the airport brings positive<br />

side-effects to FZ, since the spillovers from the administrative goodwill might lead to<br />

equally increasing community goodwill, helping to put aircraft noise in perspective<br />

with the related economic benefits.<br />

(c) internal governance. In order to honour its obligations towards the environment,<br />

FZ operates a comprehensive ISO 14001:2004 certified environmental management<br />

programme. In its endeavours to being a good corporate citizen, FZ collects<br />

124 'Welcome to Glattal!'. Retrieved August 5, 2010 from www.glow.ch/de/business/contact/.<br />

265


266<br />

Case Studies<br />

environmental data throughout <strong>and</strong> around 125 the airport, which it records, processes<br />

<strong>and</strong> systematically reports in the form <strong>of</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ardised key data. Among others, the<br />

firm continuously monitors emissions <strong>of</strong> nitrogen oxides (NOX), volatile organic<br />

compounds (VOCs), carbon monoxide (CO) <strong>and</strong> particulate matter (PM), which are<br />

the key pollutants affecting local air quality. Importantly, FZ calculates its CO2emissions<br />

in detail since 1991, in accordance with the GHG-protocol (Greenhouse<br />

Gas), <strong>and</strong> managed to reduce those emissions 126 under its direct control by<br />

approximately 30% since 1991, in spite <strong>of</strong> a 60% traffic increase in the same period. In<br />

acknowledgement <strong>of</strong> these endeavours FZ received Airport Carbon Accreditation 127 by<br />

ACI Europe in November 2010 on a high level. Through these systematic data<br />

collection activities FZ is able to surveil the current environmental situation <strong>and</strong><br />

evolvement there<strong>of</strong>. <strong>The</strong> details <strong>and</strong> results are being made transparent through<br />

publication in the firm's annual report, <strong>of</strong> which environmental reporting forms an<br />

integral part. In addition, key data on aircraft movements <strong>and</strong> noise emissions are<br />

published on a monthly basis on FZ's company website <strong>and</strong> through its monthly 'Lärm-<br />

Bulletin' publication. To make recent aircraft movements transparent to the local<br />

community, FZ publishes detailed movement tables on a daily basis on its website.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se mostly voluntary public reporting activities aim at gaining good decision bases<br />

for further improvements to environmental protection, but also at building trust with<br />

the airport's surrounding stakeholders. FZ hopes also that by having transparent <strong>and</strong><br />

reliable data at h<strong>and</strong>, the discussion on airport-related immissions can be brought to a<br />

less emotional level.<br />

Capabilities towards relational local embedding. Nurturing constructive relations<br />

with the airport's surrounding stakeholders is one <strong>of</strong> the most important factors for<br />

FZ's success <strong>and</strong> future development opportunities. However, FZ is aware, that<br />

although good relational embedding might lead to a change in tonality <strong>and</strong> better<br />

coordination processes, it will not alter the airport operation's key points <strong>of</strong> contention.<br />

(a) relational capabilities. As a means to reduce the airport's exposure to its regional<br />

stakeholders, FZ relies on a constructive dialogue which reaches beyond purely<br />

transactional information exchange. As it states in its sustainability report (2008: 17),<br />

125<br />

Outside Zurich airport’s premises, the Canton <strong>of</strong> Zurich's Office for Waste, Water, Energy <strong>and</strong><br />

Air monitors air quality in the region on behalf <strong>of</strong> FZ, using a network <strong>of</strong> monitoring stations.<br />

126<br />

Scope 1 <strong>and</strong> scope 2, according to company information.<br />

127<br />

See also 'committed to carbon reduction'. Retrieved November 15, 2010, from<br />

www.airportcarbonaccreditation.org, respectively from Zurich Airport corporate website:<br />

www.flughafen-zuerich.ch/desktopdefault.aspx/tabid-493/967_read-3624/.


Case Studies<br />

“a long-term orientation <strong>of</strong> operations at a major international airport requires a vital<br />

but also resilient relationship with the general public <strong>and</strong> politicians”. <strong>The</strong> complexity<br />

<strong>of</strong> the airport's impacts on its environment <strong>and</strong> its stakeholders' expectations make it<br />

essential to avoid disputes around special interests <strong>of</strong> individual stakeholders <strong>and</strong> to<br />

retain a synoptic view <strong>of</strong> the issues. To this end FZ nurtures an ongoing interaction<br />

with its surrounding communities under a wider perspective, which integrates the<br />

whole region around the airport in its considerations. In its relationship management,<br />

FZ uses the following platforms <strong>and</strong> channels:<br />

- regular information events <strong>and</strong> workshops with representatives <strong>of</strong> the affected<br />

municipalities (themes are chosen towards capacity-building <strong>of</strong> communities in<br />

fields which are prone to conflict <strong>and</strong> misunderst<strong>and</strong>ing, e.g. 'air traffic control<br />

<strong>and</strong> the impacts <strong>of</strong> weather', or 'overnight runway renovation')<br />

- participation in the master planning <strong>of</strong> Kloten, FZ's most important host<br />

community, with controversial discussions due to opposing interests (increased<br />

residential building activities versus prevention <strong>of</strong> growing numbers <strong>of</strong> noiseaffected<br />

citizens <strong>and</strong> thus opposition against the airport); periodical meetings<br />

between airport executives <strong>and</strong> city councils for information exchange <strong>and</strong> to<br />

maintain a constructive debating atmosphere<br />

- monthly high-level exchanges with local service partners for trust-building <strong>and</strong><br />

solution-finding to joint issues, respectively for constructive escalation<br />

- bi-monthly 'President's Talk', wherein FZ's CEO invites the CEOs <strong>of</strong> the service<br />

partners for an exchange<br />

- alliance-building with other organisations, crucial for the economic<br />

development on a regional or national scale (e.g. Economiesuisse, Zurich<br />

Tourism, Switzerl<strong>and</strong> Tourism, GLOW)<br />

- active membership in tourism-related associations (e.g. Switzerl<strong>and</strong> Convention<br />

& Incentive Bureau, Zürich Unterl<strong>and</strong> Tourismus)<br />

- events at the airport directed at involving the large public (e.g. the welcoming<br />

<strong>of</strong> the A380 in Zurich, multi-day festivals on the airport's observation deck,<br />

celebration <strong>of</strong> airport-related anniversaries, annual nature conservation walk on<br />

the airport's territory, etc.)<br />

Through its experiences in the past decade, FZ's relational capabilities have been<br />

honed <strong>and</strong> significantly gained in importance, due to the change <strong>of</strong> political climate. A<br />

number <strong>of</strong> external factors have contributed towards this development, from<br />

267


268<br />

Case Studies<br />

Germany's 2001 implementation <strong>of</strong> fly-over limitations 128 , to the grounding <strong>of</strong> the<br />

national carrier Swissair in 2001, <strong>and</strong> the sale <strong>of</strong> its successor 'Swiss International<br />

Airlines' to the German Lufthansa in 2005, which resulted in a partial loss <strong>of</strong> the local<br />

population's loyalty <strong>and</strong> tolerance towards aircraft noise. During this learning process<br />

FZ realised that it is not decisive to seek dialogue with any <strong>of</strong> the airport's<br />

stakeholders, but to carefully deploy resources for relationship management to interact<br />

with those stakeholders, who are genuinely interested in solution-finding. Particularly<br />

with regard to groups representing individual geographical areas <strong>of</strong> the airport's<br />

surroundings, the success <strong>of</strong> regular interactions crucially depends also on the other<br />

side's interest in finding majority-winning solutions. In some cases however, interest<br />

groups rather narrowly focus on special interests, employing political tactics instead.<br />

As a consequence FZ concentrates its efforts on its surrounding communities based on<br />

the intensity <strong>of</strong> their noise exposure, <strong>and</strong> on interest groups representing major parts <strong>of</strong><br />

noise-affected stakeholders, such as for example the SBFZ. With regard to its service<br />

partners, FZ established platforms for bilateral exchange in order to attain a common<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing on how to run the airport, <strong>and</strong> to address upcoming issues between the<br />

partners fast, transparent <strong>and</strong> trustingly. Moreover, FZ's multilateral platforms which<br />

are integral part <strong>of</strong> its daily operation, have contributed towards the cooperative airport<br />

culture <strong>and</strong> the high quality <strong>and</strong> efficiency at Zurich airport. <strong>The</strong> mutual embedding<br />

into the airport system <strong>and</strong> its environment helps in the daily operation <strong>and</strong> is<br />

particularly valuable in times <strong>of</strong> crisis, emergency, or in the management <strong>of</strong> inter-party<br />

conflicts.<br />

Notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing its efforts in the past years, the political development related to its<br />

operation has hindered FZ in creating a thoroughly positive environment. Although the<br />

presence <strong>of</strong> an international airport in Zurich's vicinity entails significant positive<br />

externalities for the Zurich region (cf. section (a) value share remaining in region,<br />

p.262), in the political discussion the negative externalities prevail. In the opinion <strong>of</strong><br />

FZ's former Head <strong>of</strong> Political Lobbying <strong>and</strong> Environment, this agonising development<br />

absorbs significant management resources, with a paralysing impact on FZ as an<br />

organisation. “With regard to business development <strong>of</strong> an airport such as Zurich<br />

Airport, maximum-solutions are no longer possible, nor desirable. Due to the political<br />

128 <strong>The</strong> fly-over limitations, which Germany enforced in 2001, effected a change in approach-routes to<br />

Zurich airport, thus exposing densely populated areas in the Zurich region to aircraft noise. At the time<br />

<strong>of</strong> escalation, this measure came as an external shock to the local population <strong>and</strong> consequently led to<br />

an increased urgency <strong>of</strong> the noise issue <strong>and</strong> increased interest groups' opposition to the airport's hub<br />

operation.


Case Studies<br />

complexity consensual solutions require all involved parties to scale back to their<br />

common denominator” (interview N°23: 11). Thus, it would be desirable for FZ to<br />

retract itself somewhat from the debates, allowing it to resolve a number <strong>of</strong> issues <strong>and</strong><br />

processes more smoothly (cf. interview N°23: 10).<br />

In its international activities, FZ gives equally high priority to the local relationship<br />

building, with better prospects to accumulate valuable goodwill stocks. To intensify<br />

relations on the institutional dimension in its Bangalore operations for example, the<br />

local operator BIAL is member in three chambers <strong>of</strong> commerce, each helping it to<br />

grow the network <strong>and</strong> to nurture contacts with important opinion makers. In addition,<br />

specific to the cultural context, the personal contact <strong>of</strong> executive management to<br />

politicians is sought regularly, in order to build goodwill stocks <strong>and</strong> to reduce overall<br />

transaction costs <strong>and</strong> institutional risks. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, BIAL tries to establish a<br />

relation with the local community through regular festivals on the airport site <strong>and</strong><br />

events in cooperation with the various tourism associations, which - apart from the<br />

advertising effect - positively connect the airport with the touristic symbols <strong>of</strong> national<br />

<strong>and</strong> local pride. Furthermore, related to its next big expansion phase, BIAL has<br />

organised a competition for architectural students with regard to design proposals for<br />

the new terminal building. Equally with the motivation to build goodwill stocks for the<br />

airport's extension, BIAL has become a leader in the use <strong>of</strong> social media - among<br />

others - with the launch <strong>of</strong> its 'smilebengaluru' initiative (www.smilebengaluru.com) in<br />

2010, through which it involves the local community <strong>and</strong> airport users in the design<br />

<strong>and</strong> features for the new parts <strong>of</strong> the airport.<br />

(b) reputation-building capabilities. <strong>The</strong> political sensitivity <strong>and</strong> strategic importance<br />

<strong>of</strong> the airport business make reputation management a key capability <strong>of</strong> operators. In<br />

the case <strong>of</strong> FZ's Zurich operation, its importance is further underlined through the<br />

objectives specified by FZ's public shareholder, the Canton <strong>of</strong> Zurich. Thus, FZ<br />

engages in a number <strong>of</strong> activities to build stakeholder awareness on the airport's role<br />

for local value creation, but also its efforts towards environmental protection <strong>and</strong><br />

emission reduction. Its 'green' activities in Zurich include:<br />

- the promotion <strong>of</strong> more environmentally friendly aircraft through incentivising<br />

airport charges (reduction <strong>of</strong> noise, air pollutants, CO2 emissions 129 ) - the<br />

129 In its annual report (2010: 16), FZ states: “Minimising noise immissions wherever possible is a<br />

high priority for Flughafen Zürich AG, <strong>and</strong> is set to remain that way. Admittedly, it will not be easy to<br />

reconcile the dem<strong>and</strong> for mobility with the need for noise reduction in the coming years.”<br />

Furthermore: "We are committed to ensuring that aviation evolves in an environmentally-friendly<br />

269


270<br />

Case Studies<br />

current charges are in the process <strong>of</strong> being adapted in two-steps in order to<br />

reflect the technological advances <strong>and</strong> to keep up the incentivising effect;<br />

- incentives for employees (in the form <strong>of</strong> a public transport pass as fringe<br />

benefit) <strong>and</strong> airport users (through high parking fees as negative incentive) to<br />

avoid private transport <strong>and</strong> use trains <strong>and</strong> buses instead;<br />

- the instalment <strong>of</strong> environmentally friendly building structures <strong>and</strong> business<br />

processes, which limit the airport's energy consumption (e.g. through the use <strong>of</strong><br />

geothermics) <strong>and</strong> reduce impacts on the environment (e.g. through the recycling<br />

<strong>of</strong> de-icing agents);<br />

- the maintenance <strong>of</strong> the nature conservation zone around FZ's airport perimeter<br />

through the airport's green area maintenance crew; <strong>and</strong><br />

- the environmental supervision <strong>of</strong> construction projects through strict internally<br />

developed environmental protection regulations, which FZ considers as its<br />

ecological st<strong>and</strong>ards.<br />

While stakeholders in its Zurich-operation expect mainly an environmental focus from<br />

FZ, in its international activities equally a social orientation is expected for FZ's<br />

organisational legitimisation. For example in its Bengaluru project, its local operator<br />

company established a CSR programme to support the villagers around the airport.<br />

Importantly, irrespective <strong>of</strong> the degree <strong>of</strong> their environment's economic development,<br />

airports need to inform their local stakeholders on their contribution towards the<br />

economy, <strong>and</strong> to legitimise themselves on the basis <strong>of</strong> the strategic importance <strong>of</strong> their<br />

infrastructure. After an initial learning process, particularly in FZ's Bengaluru<br />

operation, where image <strong>and</strong> reputation were essential factors in the opening process<br />

for its greenfield airport, FZ successfully builds the reputations <strong>of</strong> its international<br />

airports in their environments. <strong>The</strong>reby it always takes into consideration the political<br />

dimension <strong>of</strong> its airport operation <strong>and</strong> the public dimension, adopting the reputationbuilding<br />

approaches accordingly. With regard to Bengaluru International Airport, the<br />

early reputational difficulties have been overcome altogether in the meantime: the<br />

airport has successfully built a local <strong>and</strong> national reputation as India's most efficient<br />

airport <strong>and</strong> receives prestigious awards, such as the CNBC Awaaz Award as India's<br />

'Best managed Airport' in 2010.<br />

(c) capabilities to adapt to the local environment. One <strong>of</strong> FZ's key strengths lies in its<br />

strong industry knowledge, combined with the awareness that an airport is an<br />

manner. Our aim is to further reduce the CO2 emissions we cause, while taking into account the<br />

general legal <strong>and</strong> economic framework” (ibid.: 55).


Case Studies<br />

infrastructure <strong>of</strong> national <strong>and</strong> regional pride, i.e. which needs to be adapted to local<br />

customs. This is not only expressed in an airport's architecture, but also in<br />

organisational structures, processes <strong>and</strong> control mechanisms, employment terms, <strong>and</strong><br />

the h<strong>and</strong>ling <strong>of</strong> stakeholders in the airport's environment. A best-practice example in<br />

FZ's international activities can be found in its engagement as airport operator in<br />

Curacao, where it is active since 2009. Before assuming operational responsibility, FZ<br />

initiated a stakeholder dialogue, where it outlined its own operational philosophy <strong>and</strong>,<br />

more importantly, familiarised itself with stakeholder expectations. This road show has<br />

been prepared by a local public relations specialist, with pr<strong>of</strong>ound knowledge <strong>of</strong> the<br />

political circumstances. In preparation, FZ received a stakeholder map with all critical<br />

issues, thus being sensitively aware <strong>of</strong> the history <strong>of</strong> the airport's stakeholder relations,<br />

as well as the stakeholder concerns. In the course <strong>of</strong> these discussions, the parties<br />

achieved consensus on common objectives for the airport <strong>and</strong> its development. As a<br />

result, the new airport operator was supported from the very beginning by its<br />

stakeholders, including the local population, the regulator, trade unions <strong>and</strong> the<br />

airport's employees. Moreover, the government approached it for support in the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> a strategic l<strong>and</strong> reserve beneath the dedicated perimeter, which it<br />

earmarked for this purpose. Consequently, FZ agreed to further evaluate if any larger<br />

scale projects would be economically viable. In the meantime, FZ has initiated a major<br />

l<strong>and</strong>side development programme, which includes the development <strong>and</strong> construction<br />

<strong>of</strong> an anchor project under its own risk in order to attract further interested parties, thus<br />

vitally stimulating the local economy. Importantly, from the beginning <strong>of</strong> its<br />

engagement in Curacao FZ was able to apprehend the local expectations <strong>and</strong> to<br />

adequately adapt, while at the same time engaging itself in the economic development<br />

<strong>of</strong> the isl<strong>and</strong>.<br />

In its airport operation in Bengaluru, India FZ has gone through a learning process<br />

towards recognising local needs <strong>and</strong> subsequent local adaptation. After initially<br />

focusing primarily on airport efficiency for passengers <strong>and</strong> cargo, FZ has recognised<br />

the high significance <strong>of</strong> VIP's in India, which led to adaptation <strong>of</strong> airport infrastructure<br />

<strong>and</strong> processes. Through these status-lending procedures it <strong>of</strong>fers VIP's <strong>and</strong> VVIP's the<br />

respect <strong>and</strong> treatment that is expected in the Indian context. Consequently, it not only<br />

conforms to local convention, but at the same time has improved its relationship with<br />

the local, regional, <strong>and</strong> even national opinion-makers.<br />

In general, to fuse its industry knowledge with the local customs for best leverage, FZ<br />

works with locally embedded <strong>and</strong> respected partners, which help it to overcome its<br />

liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness (cf. p.276). With regard to FZ's best practice knowledge, its<br />

271


272<br />

Case Studies<br />

success is less related to the know-how itself, but to the capability <strong>of</strong> its experts to<br />

adapt it to the local context, <strong>and</strong> to the experts' intercultural sensitivity. For example,<br />

while an airport in Chile or India equally benefits from the introduction <strong>of</strong><br />

collaborative decision making (CDM) in its operations, it might not yet need the<br />

sophisticated s<strong>of</strong>tware, which FZ effectively employs at Zurich airport. However,<br />

more importantly the CDM philosophy needs to be imparted on the local employees.<br />

Depending on the local culture <strong>and</strong> the markedness <strong>of</strong> power distance, the idea <strong>of</strong><br />

expressing one's own judgment on a situation in daily airport management <strong>and</strong> to take<br />

responsibility for consequent decisions mean a major change in organisational culture.<br />

Thus, the effective scaling <strong>of</strong> the processes <strong>and</strong> tools to the size <strong>and</strong> needs <strong>of</strong> the<br />

airport, but also to the respective local culture ultimately decides on the value created<br />

through best practice transfer (cf. interview N°13).<br />

5.2.7 Value creation<br />

As an airport operator from a country with dem<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>and</strong> critical stakeholders in<br />

respect <strong>of</strong> the airport's growth perspectives, with spatial <strong>and</strong> capacity limitations <strong>and</strong><br />

with high employment cost, FZ is used to (1) attune its company goals with its<br />

complex institutional environment, (2) focus on quality as a means to satisfy its<br />

various stakeholders, <strong>and</strong> (3) to achieve <strong>and</strong> continuously improve its high levels <strong>of</strong><br />

efficiency. <strong>The</strong>se three firm characteristics are important in its Zurich operation <strong>and</strong> in<br />

its approach to international projects pertaining to value creation. <strong>The</strong> subsequent<br />

sections discuss value creation aspects <strong>of</strong> FZ's activities from a single- <strong>and</strong> multi-site<br />

perspective.<br />

(1) single-site perspective. Despite its limited flexibility grounded in its local<br />

exposure FZ is able to create value through its embedding capabilities. In its Zurich<br />

operations its credibility with the regulator, <strong>and</strong> its excellent track-record as a worldclass<br />

airport operator give FZ's lobbying more weight - at least in those areas, which<br />

are not touching political focal points. Particularly in its commercial activities FZ is<br />

therefore able to create valuable strategic options. An example where its pro-active<br />

relationship management <strong>and</strong> communication efforts led to such options is found in the<br />

subject <strong>of</strong> regulatory smoking bans in public areas. Early in the legislative process for<br />

formulating the new law, FZ began to develop concepts for br<strong>and</strong>ed smoking lounges<br />

in cooperation with tobacco firms. <strong>The</strong>se lounges were constructed on a sponsoring<br />

basis, generating significant advertising revenues. By proactively approaching the<br />

legislator with concrete amendment proposals for the wording <strong>of</strong> the law, FZ was able<br />

to anchor its concept legally <strong>and</strong> to further pursue the sponsoring concept, despite a


Case Studies<br />

general ban <strong>of</strong> tobacco advertising. In another example, FZ succeeded in an<br />

amendment <strong>of</strong> the law with regard to the airport's l<strong>and</strong>side traffic. Due to an increasing<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> for direct transportation for tourists from the airport to the skiing regions in<br />

winter, FZ started to lobby for obtaining regulatory approval to <strong>of</strong>fer bus services.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se activities finally led to an amendment <strong>of</strong> the law, resulting in increased revenues<br />

<strong>and</strong> higher service quality for winter tourists. In its most recent lobbying efforts FZ<br />

worked towards one <strong>of</strong> its biggest strategic options for non-aeronautical revenues: a<br />

licence for arrival duty free, which ultimately was approved in December 2010 <strong>and</strong><br />

will allow it to increase its retail revenues, thus creating further options for growth.<br />

Also in its international activities FZ creates strategic options through its close<br />

cooperation with local partners <strong>and</strong> its relationship building with the surrounding<br />

stakeholders, particularly with the public authorities, as the example <strong>of</strong> Curacao<br />

illustrates (cf. p.271). In contrast, the example <strong>of</strong> Bengaluru International Airport<br />

shows, how a neglect <strong>of</strong> pro-active relationship management may lead to foregone<br />

options. In the greenfield project's construction <strong>and</strong> start-up phase, FZ underestimated<br />

the intensity with which relations to Indian authorities need to be cultivated. Thus, the<br />

local operator BIAL faced a number <strong>of</strong> obstacles which might have been avoided<br />

otherwise. BIAL's plan to erect an airport hotel next to the terminal for example was<br />

blocked for more than a year due to a local l<strong>and</strong> development authority's refusal to<br />

approve its initial construction plans. This came partly as a result <strong>of</strong> BIAL's neglect to<br />

involve the authorities at an early stage <strong>and</strong> to clarify possible exemptions with respect<br />

to the local building code. Consequently, the authority decided to disapprove the<br />

requested building height <strong>and</strong> to allow only the 35% lower legal maximum height,<br />

which would have rendered the planned hotel operation economically unviable. After<br />

prolonged negotiations with the authorities, BIAL decided to adapt its construction<br />

plans <strong>and</strong> to increase the lateral size <strong>of</strong> the hotel plot (cf. interview N°15), which<br />

ultimately got approved by the authorities.<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the key objectives <strong>of</strong> FZ's embedding efforts is a decrease <strong>of</strong> the risks from its<br />

local exposure. <strong>The</strong> effectiveness <strong>of</strong> these efforts, however, significantly depends on a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> external parameters which are difficult to influence, as the case <strong>of</strong> the<br />

operations in Zurich shows. Beyond FZ's influence, for example, is the instalment <strong>of</strong> a<br />

new air-space related Administrative Agreement 130 between Switzerl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Germany.<br />

In 2001, Germany unilaterally terminated the previous agreement, replacing it with<br />

German Implementation Regulations (DVO). <strong>The</strong>se resulted in tightened flight<br />

130 I.e. 'Verwaltungsvereinbarung'.<br />

273


274<br />

Case Studies<br />

restrictions for Zurich Airport on weekends <strong>and</strong> holidays. A decade later, the<br />

conciliation between the two nations on the DVO is still pending. Under such<br />

institutional circumstances, <strong>and</strong> under consideration <strong>of</strong> the multiplexity <strong>of</strong> its<br />

stakeholders' interests, FZ's levers to reduce its institutional risks are limited. To<br />

address these external parameters, FZ may hope on the Canton <strong>of</strong> Zurich's engagement<br />

in its interest, as its majority shareholder, <strong>and</strong> on the federal government, which has a<br />

strategic interest in the functioning <strong>of</strong> the airport as a central transport infrastructure.<br />

With regard to regulatory <strong>and</strong> political risks, FZ's local embedding with its system<br />

partners has a risk-decreasing impact. <strong>The</strong> resulting consistent high level <strong>of</strong> quality<br />

reassures the authorities that the airport is competent to perform in accordance with its<br />

m<strong>and</strong>ate. As long as FZ proves its pr<strong>of</strong>essionalism in airport operations <strong>and</strong><br />

maintenance, regulatory bodies have no need for interventions <strong>and</strong> closer monitoring<br />

beyond the necessary. As a result,the public shareholder's framework for FZ's<br />

performance management only lays down high-level performance indicators <strong>and</strong><br />

leaves FZ's management flexibility in how to attain them. Aware <strong>of</strong> this comfortable<br />

room for manoeuvre FZ is highly motivated to continuously improve its quality<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ards, such as to keep these regulatory <strong>and</strong> political risks low (interview N°17). In<br />

contrast, British airports for example, which are less exemplary in their reinvestment<br />

<strong>and</strong> service levels, have a rather tense relationship with the regulator. <strong>The</strong> latter's<br />

mistrust resulted in its decision to tightly monitor airports, prescribing price <strong>and</strong><br />

quality <strong>and</strong> thus exposing airports to higher risks with respect to regulatory action.<br />

In the short-term FZ creates value in its Zurich operations, but also in its international<br />

airport operations, on the following dimensions:<br />

- Transaction costs: after a learning process in its international activities with regard<br />

to legitimacy-building, FZ is able to decrease transaction costs <strong>and</strong> the time to<br />

implementation in business development, as the example <strong>of</strong> its Curacao activities<br />

illustrates. Meanwhile, its embedding capabilities allow it to lower the legal costs<br />

in international airport operations. In its Zurich operations, FZ is able to lower<br />

transaction costs with surrounding communities, as illustrated in the GLOWexample,<br />

whereas it is not able to realise transaction cost savings on the political<br />

dimension. <strong>The</strong>re, its efforts seem to be overridden by external factors, on which it<br />

has little influence.<br />

- Operational efficiency: FZ's embedding capabilities, high legitimacy, <strong>and</strong> trusting<br />

relationship with its service partners contribute to lower cost <strong>of</strong> interaction in daily<br />

airport operation, <strong>and</strong> to better decisions - particularly through its collaborative


Case Studies<br />

decision-making philosophy - which further improve service quality <strong>and</strong> efficiency.<br />

In Zurich, its constructive working relationship <strong>and</strong> optimal information exchange<br />

with Skyguide, the air traffic control provider, also leads to better utilisation <strong>of</strong><br />

limited runway capacity, subject to compliance with safety st<strong>and</strong>ards.<br />

- Valorisation <strong>of</strong> by-products: Airports' most significant by-product is the number <strong>of</strong><br />

people they attract, owing to their activities <strong>and</strong> in their function as a natural nodal<br />

point. In Zurich, FZ has been able to exploit <strong>and</strong> increase the location's<br />

attractiveness by exp<strong>and</strong>ing its <strong>of</strong>fer for l<strong>and</strong>side shopping 131 , <strong>and</strong> by developing<br />

business <strong>and</strong> convention facilities, including <strong>of</strong>fice-space in the high-price<br />

segment. Thus, it attracts further visitors, who are not primarily interested in the<br />

airport's core services. This development has been reinforced by the lobbying<br />

efforts <strong>of</strong> FZ's commercial <strong>and</strong> real estate developers, e.g. with regard to special<br />

opening hours, <strong>and</strong> by the success <strong>of</strong> its home carrier Swiss International Airlines.<br />

<strong>The</strong> high popularity <strong>of</strong> the airport as an excursion destination reflects the<br />

legitimacy <strong>and</strong> goodwill it receives from the local population, despite the<br />

unpopular issue <strong>of</strong> aviation noise. With regard to FZ's international activities, the<br />

commercial development <strong>of</strong> its portfolio airports represents one <strong>of</strong> its strategic<br />

pillars for value creation.<br />

(2) multi-site perspective. Although airports are highly location-dependent, their<br />

design <strong>and</strong> operational procedures are internationally regulated (ICAO <strong>and</strong> EU<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ards), contributing to global st<strong>and</strong>ardisation. In this respect, FZ's former Head <strong>of</strong><br />

Corporate <strong>Projects</strong> observes: “With regard to our international expansion this<br />

regulatory st<strong>and</strong>ardisation is a major industry advantage. To build <strong>and</strong> operate airports<br />

in other countries FZ can rely on the knowledge, which it has acquired through its<br />

airport operation in Zurich” (interview N°22: 2). Thus, it is able to employ its<br />

operational <strong>and</strong> commercial knowledge independent <strong>of</strong> any location. FZ's motivation<br />

for its internationalisation strategy can be summarised as follows, according to a<br />

company presentation (Grünig, 2009: slide 30):<br />

Growth opportunities on the basis <strong>of</strong><br />

- FZ's reputation as ‘Europe’s Leading Airport’<br />

- Competencies <strong>and</strong> knowhow as precondition for successful international<br />

engagements<br />

- Swiss values <strong>and</strong> characteristics, e.g. reliability, efficiency, cleanliness, etc.<br />

- Project experience in India <strong>and</strong> South America since 1999<br />

131 Zurich airport is Switzerl<strong>and</strong>'s second largest shopping centre in terms <strong>of</strong> annual turnover (2010).<br />

275


276<br />

Additional benefits on the basis <strong>of</strong><br />

- Knowledge transfer<br />

- Benchmarking with other airports<br />

- Broadening <strong>of</strong> horizon for employees<br />

- Job enrichment <strong>and</strong> more attractive pr<strong>of</strong>essional perspectives<br />

Case Studies<br />

Since FZ, as a partially state-owned enterprise does not possess the financial means for<br />

major equity participations, its international strategic orientation aims at airport<br />

management contracts, where it is able to fruitfully transfer the whole range <strong>of</strong> its<br />

operational know-how <strong>and</strong> best practice procedures.<br />

(a) relations. Due to the (sometimes hurtful) experiences in the earliest international<br />

airport projects, FZ has been able to accumulate valuable capabilities with regard to<br />

legitimisation processes abroad. Today, FZ's reputation for quality <strong>and</strong><br />

pr<strong>of</strong>essionalism, <strong>and</strong> for its cooperative approach, lends it credibility <strong>and</strong><br />

trustworthiness in its project acquisitions. Moreover, its credibility is further reinforced<br />

by its track-record in Zurich, where it is ranked among the top European airports for a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> years now. <strong>The</strong> company also exploits its advantage <strong>of</strong> having a Swiss<br />

background, which internationally is associated with a number <strong>of</strong> positive<br />

characteristics, such as reliability, pr<strong>of</strong>essionalism, efficiency <strong>and</strong> effectiveness. With<br />

these combined signalling qualities, FZ is very effective in approaching countries with<br />

upcoming airport privatisations <strong>and</strong> in opening doors with regulators <strong>and</strong><br />

administrations. Its reputation also facilitates the finding <strong>of</strong> strong <strong>and</strong> trustworthy<br />

local partners.<br />

In its international airport projects, FZ meanwhile has also been able to establish a few<br />

show-cases <strong>of</strong> its involvements. <strong>The</strong>se references demonstrate not only economic<br />

effectiveness, but also FZ's ability to engage with the local communities <strong>and</strong> to respect<br />

the local culture in its airport management approach. Based on its experiences, FZ puts<br />

high importance to the cooperation with a strong locally embedded partner, who<br />

supports it in establishing the operation in situ. Under this set-up, the privatised<br />

airports, which <strong>of</strong>ten face initial distrust due to their new status, are able to establish<br />

themselves more effectively <strong>and</strong> to earn their licence to operate. Thus, FZ's ability to<br />

combine its own industry knowledge with the local strengths <strong>of</strong> its carefully selected<br />

partners effectively helps it to overcome the liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness.<br />

(b) resources. Through a number <strong>of</strong> influences, FZ has been forced to develop best<br />

practices, which allow it to be highly efficient <strong>and</strong> to maximise the safe use <strong>of</strong> limited<br />

capacity. Among the main reasons are its long experience as operator <strong>of</strong> a secondary


Case Studies<br />

hub, the high labour costs in Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> the difficult local environment inhibiting<br />

further capacity expansion. Its know-how <strong>and</strong> its underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> quality therefore<br />

have contributed to its reputation as a world-class airport operator. In its international<br />

activities it effectively transfers this knowledge to less developed airport operations.<br />

Its business model rests on the acquisition <strong>and</strong> management <strong>of</strong> international projects<br />

through a separate department, whereas the expert know-how resides within the whole<br />

organisation which operates Zurich airport. Whenever particular skills are needed, the<br />

business development unit draws on the respective experts, who appreciate the<br />

opportunity to engage in international projects. Thus, FZ not only transfers theoretical<br />

knowledge, but also the expertise to apply it in new environments.<br />

Such in-depth familiarity with the rules, combined with capabilities for the practical<br />

adaptation <strong>of</strong> know-how, seems to be particularly important in the complex airport<br />

business. In its projects in Bangalore <strong>and</strong> Bogota, FZ became involved in time to<br />

review earlier inputs from external consultants. Although these were fully in<br />

accordance with the ICAO rules <strong>and</strong> regulations, they would have rendered an<br />

efficient operation impossible. As an experienced airport operator, FZ was able to<br />

identify <strong>and</strong> correct these flaws in the planning stage. FZ's value creation in its<br />

international activities thus primarily relates to its fusing <strong>of</strong> operational requirements<br />

<strong>and</strong> commercial knowhow <strong>and</strong> includes the areas as detailed in Table 5-6.<br />

Type <strong>of</strong><br />

synergy<br />

operative<br />

synergies<br />

Organisat.<br />

level<br />

grouplevel<br />

cross-site<br />

level;<br />

grouplevel<br />

(continued next page)<br />

Examples<br />

Best practice transfer from FZ to its international airports (i.e. airport<br />

planning processes <strong>and</strong> tools, manuals <strong>and</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard operating procedures<br />

in airport operation, etc.): while the knowledge needs to be adapted, the<br />

transfer <strong>of</strong> proven systems <strong>and</strong> processes improves productivity <strong>and</strong> saves<br />

resources, respectively reduces costs <strong>of</strong> trial <strong>and</strong> error.<br />

Best practice exchange between the airports, where FZ is involved as<br />

operator <strong>and</strong> investor: through exchanges between similarly sized airports,<br />

which experience similar issues in their respective countries (e.g. coping<br />

with regulatory uncertainty from ongoing privatisation processes,<br />

argumentation strategies towards regulators <strong>and</strong> boards <strong>of</strong> directors with<br />

state-involvement, etc.), economies <strong>of</strong> experience may be realised.<br />

FZ is in the process <strong>of</strong> institutionalising the exchange between these<br />

airports <strong>and</strong> to set up platforms for regular interaction.<br />

277


278<br />

Type <strong>of</strong><br />

synergy<br />

market<br />

power<br />

synergies<br />

Organisat.<br />

level<br />

grouplevel<br />

cross-site;<br />

grouplevel<br />

regional<br />

level<br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel<br />

(continued next page)<br />

Examples<br />

Case Studies<br />

<strong>The</strong> international experience increases the overall quality <strong>of</strong> FZ's<br />

management: executives <strong>and</strong> specialists draw beneficial insights <strong>and</strong><br />

impulses from benchmarking their own practices against alternative<br />

(sometimes simpler <strong>and</strong> thus less costly) approaches. Through the<br />

international experiences <strong>of</strong> FZ's Zurich-based specialists, FZ creates a<br />

management pool, be it for deployment to other international operations,<br />

or ultimately for recruitment <strong>of</strong> the next management generation at its own<br />

home base.<br />

Compliance support <strong>and</strong> consulting with regard to the implementation <strong>and</strong><br />

interpretation <strong>of</strong> international <strong>and</strong> national regulations: due to regulatory<br />

discretion, economies <strong>of</strong> experience save costs <strong>of</strong> non-compliance <strong>and</strong><br />

trial <strong>and</strong> error.<br />

Economies <strong>of</strong> scope: in its Latin American engagements, FZ (respectively<br />

its joint venture 'A-Port') is able to realise economies <strong>of</strong> scope through the<br />

management <strong>of</strong> small airport systems. <strong>The</strong> operation <strong>and</strong> administration <strong>of</strong><br />

four small-scale airports in Honduras, for example, is coordinated through<br />

one top-management team.<br />

Purchasing: while FZ has no centralised value-chain activities for its<br />

airport portfolio, negotiation advantages can be realised to a small extent<br />

on the basis <strong>of</strong> its product know-how <strong>and</strong> its supplier network. With FZ's<br />

expertise, modernising airports therefore are able to create value from<br />

more effective purchasing processes <strong>and</strong> consequently from better supplier<br />

decisions.<br />

However, depending on applicability <strong>of</strong> WTO/GATT procurement<br />

regulations at the involved airports, joint purchasing efforts are inhibited.<br />

Potentially at some point in time, FZ could achieve savings in its airport<br />

portfolio with regard to industry-specific ICT systems, ICT hardware, or<br />

specific vehicles <strong>and</strong> equipment (e.g. fire trucks, passenger boarding<br />

bridges, tow back vehicles, etc.).<br />

Economies <strong>of</strong> experience in airport concession negotiations for new<br />

international projects: with an increasing number <strong>of</strong> airports in its<br />

portfolio, FZ builds its negotiation capabilities, resulting in the realisation<br />

<strong>of</strong> more favourable bid prices for any airport value-chain activities that it<br />

outsources by means <strong>of</strong> licensing.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se economies also apply to the negotiations with consortium partners,<br />

regarding the cooperation mode <strong>and</strong> conditions for the venture.<br />

Bundling synergies in service partner <strong>and</strong> concessionaire licencing:<br />

Prospective service partners possibly bid more aggressively for<br />

commercial licences at individual airport locations, if FZ operates a<br />

portfolio <strong>of</strong> airports with interesting future opportunities for the bidders.


Case Studies<br />

Type <strong>of</strong><br />

synergy<br />

financial<br />

synergies<br />

corporate<br />

mgmt.<br />

synergies<br />

Organisat.<br />

level<br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel<br />

Examples<br />

Return-maximising investment <strong>of</strong> surpluses, which are generated in FZ's<br />

Zurich operation: Given the limited growth opportunities in Zurich,<br />

international airport activities provide means to grow <strong>and</strong> to create value<br />

beyond the possibilities in the financial market. Thus, FZ's surplus<br />

financial means can be employed abroad in a value-enhancing way.<br />

Reduced overall business risk due to a geographically wide-spread airport<br />

portfolio, which follows different economic cycles: risk reduction is<br />

particularly important in view <strong>of</strong> FZ's dependence <strong>and</strong> risk concentration<br />

towards Star Alliance in its Zurich operation (with a Star Alliance<br />

passenger share <strong>of</strong> 71.6%).<br />

Better access to capital: FZ as an airport group is able to obtain more<br />

favourable conditions, compared to the financing possibilities <strong>of</strong><br />

individual small-scale airports.<br />

Organisational design: from its experiences <strong>and</strong> particularly from the<br />

lessons drawn from its own past miscues, FZ knows which type <strong>of</strong> airport<br />

<strong>and</strong> institutional environment requires what kind <strong>of</strong> organisational<br />

structure, in order to perform smoothly. Through its capabilities to adapt<br />

locally, FZ is sensitive to local specificities, enabling it to draw valid<br />

conclusions for its organisational approach.<br />

Improved overall long-term planning: FZ's strategic capabilities have been<br />

honed through its international 'greenfield' experiences, which is<br />

beneficial also to its Zurich operations. From its acquired insights into the<br />

building <strong>of</strong> new airports, including long-term masterplanning in multiple<br />

phases, FZ has received impulses for its approach to long-term planning at<br />

its homebase, as well as for its acquisitions <strong>of</strong> further greenfield <strong>and</strong><br />

airport expansion projects (cf. interview N° 22).<br />

Table 5-6: Overview on Zurich airport’s synergy implementation<br />

Because the internationalisation <strong>of</strong> the airport industry has a relatively young history,<br />

FZ is only at the beginning <strong>of</strong> structuring the exchange between its airport operations.<br />

Until recently, any knowledge transfer was channelled through its business<br />

development department in Zurich, <strong>and</strong> there was no direct exchange between the<br />

related airports. However, the firm has recognised the value-creation potential <strong>of</strong> such<br />

additional links <strong>and</strong> is in the process <strong>of</strong> setting up structures <strong>and</strong> platforms for a more<br />

dynamic interchange.<br />

(c) institutions. Based on the experiences at Zurich airport <strong>and</strong> the related institutional<br />

environment, in its international activities FZ knows exactly where internationally<br />

proven best-practice procedures are required, <strong>and</strong> - in contrast - where local<br />

279


280<br />

Case Studies<br />

knowledge is needed in order to manage an operation successfully. Thus, apart from<br />

the internationally applicable regulatory knowledge, which FZ has internalised, the<br />

firm employs carefully selected local specialists with regard to h<strong>and</strong>ling the local<br />

political system, authorities <strong>and</strong> institutions, as well as other stakeholders, where FZ<br />

could experience liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness. As FZ's former Head <strong>of</strong> Corporate <strong>Projects</strong><br />

states (cf. interview N°22: 3):<br />

Being an international airport operator, it is essential to have a competent local<br />

partner at h<strong>and</strong>, who h<strong>and</strong>les the politically sensitive issues. As we have seen in our<br />

greenfield project in Bangalore, India the existence <strong>of</strong> such a strong <strong>and</strong> locally<br />

embedded strategic partner turned out to be decisive for our project's success. Such<br />

a partner needs to be able to deal with the authorities <strong>and</strong> the regulator at different<br />

spatial scales. What we learned in India was also, that it is not enough to have<br />

contacts on the business level, but that the network <strong>of</strong> political relations <strong>and</strong> the<br />

degree <strong>of</strong> influence <strong>and</strong> power decide in the end. <strong>The</strong>re are countries, where it is<br />

more important to have the right partner than to do the things right.<br />

With regard to FZ's compliance monitoring, its effectiveness depends on the type <strong>of</strong><br />

contract <strong>and</strong> involvement in its international engagements. In Bangalore for example,<br />

FZ occupies a seat in the board <strong>of</strong> directors <strong>and</strong> is responsible for recruitment <strong>of</strong> the<br />

airport's top management. Thus, it is able to take influence on the airport's<br />

performance, <strong>and</strong> to initiate corrective actions in case <strong>of</strong> underperformance, for<br />

example by dispatching specialists from its Zurich operations for analysis <strong>and</strong> support.<br />

Apart from the joint devising <strong>of</strong> the airport's financial management information system<br />

(MIS) <strong>and</strong> the operational key performance indicators, FZ regularly evaluates the<br />

airport's sensitive areas, such as safety <strong>and</strong> security, airport maintenance, <strong>and</strong> daily<br />

operational processes. <strong>The</strong>se engagements are understood as system checks in order to<br />

uncover improvement potentials <strong>and</strong> continue the transfer <strong>of</strong> specific best practices.<br />

On the other h<strong>and</strong>, its involvement as an internationally recognised airport operator<br />

gives FZ clout in the political support <strong>and</strong> the regulatory lobbying for its international<br />

projects. Its CEO, COO <strong>and</strong> top level business developers selectively pay curtesy visits<br />

to their host countries' authorities <strong>and</strong> aviation ministers, or specifically lobby for FZ's<br />

interests in the individual local operations. In many <strong>of</strong> the countries, where FZ engages<br />

in airport operations, the privatisation process <strong>of</strong> the airport industry has only begun,<br />

including the necessary regulatory <strong>and</strong> legal amendments. Thus, FZ is not only<br />

exposed to uncertainty, but simultaneously has the opportunity to take influence on the<br />

regulatory system towards international compatibility <strong>and</strong> serving its interests as an


Case Studies<br />

international airport operator. In India, for example, FZ became involved with the<br />

regulator during a major reform <strong>of</strong> airport regulation. In this process, it was able to<br />

transfer know-how on regulatory frameworks <strong>and</strong> experiences with the Swiss<br />

regulatory system to the national authorities (cf. interview N°15).<br />

5.2.8 Summary<br />

FZ's location-fixity stems from all three identified dimensions: its resourcedependence,<br />

the dependence on being close to its market, <strong>and</strong> from its public<br />

shareholders. <strong>The</strong> resulting local exposure is closely related to the nature <strong>of</strong> FZ's<br />

externalities, which affect significant parts <strong>of</strong> the wider local population. In addition,<br />

the airport is exposed due to a number <strong>of</strong> political factors which are beyond its sphere<br />

<strong>of</strong> influence, such as the restrictions to using German territory for approaches <strong>and</strong><br />

take-<strong>of</strong>fs. In this challenging environment, FZ has learned to invest in embedding<br />

activities where they are most effective, such the fostering <strong>of</strong> dialogues with<br />

principally constructive interest groups, or the active relationship management <strong>and</strong><br />

capacity-building with representatives from politics <strong>and</strong> local administrations in the<br />

surrounding municipalities.<br />

As a consequence <strong>of</strong> the restrictions in its home environment, FZ is able to create<br />

value in its international business development <strong>and</strong> to deploy its financial means,<br />

which cannot be equally fruitfully used in its Zurich operation. Overall, these multisite<br />

activities create value for the individual international operations, but also for its<br />

homebase in Zurich through the benchmarking effect between its operations. <strong>The</strong><br />

insights into various problem-solving approaches in its portfolio provide FZ with the<br />

possibility to positively stimulate the dynamics <strong>and</strong> competitiveness within its<br />

portfolio. FZ's former Chief Development Officer observes: “If a firm is location-fix<br />

<strong>and</strong> at the same time enjoys a natural monopoly, the pressure for improvements in<br />

efficiency <strong>and</strong> quality are less intense than in competitive environments. Thus, our<br />

internationalisation is an important factor for us to remain pr<strong>of</strong>essional <strong>and</strong> to ensure<br />

long-term survival” (interview N°24: 6).<br />

281


282<br />

5.3 Case study - cement <strong>and</strong> building materials<br />

Case Studies<br />

<strong>The</strong> cement 132 industry developed in the course <strong>of</strong> the 19 th century, driven by the<br />

industrial revolution, when evolving needs for infrastructure required new solutions<br />

for building materials. Equally, new production technologies <strong>and</strong> the advent <strong>of</strong> railway<br />

infrastructure allowed the industry to grow in efficiency <strong>and</strong> to consolidate, since<br />

transportation <strong>of</strong> the bulky product became less costly.<br />

Modern cement-production is energy-consuming <strong>and</strong> entails significant<br />

environmentally unfriendly emissions. It can be divided in two main stages: the<br />

transformation <strong>of</strong> raw limestone <strong>and</strong> smaller quantities <strong>of</strong> clay, shale <strong>and</strong> s<strong>and</strong>, into<br />

clinker at temperatures <strong>of</strong> 1'400°C, <strong>and</strong> the milling <strong>of</strong> clinker with other minerals to<br />

produce the cement powder. Plants generally locate nearby limestone quarries to<br />

minimise transportation costs <strong>and</strong> to ensure security <strong>of</strong> raw-material supply. Figure<br />

5-10 illustrates the cement production process <strong>and</strong> its associated externalities.<br />

Owing to the fact, that cement production is responsible for approximately 5% <strong>of</strong><br />

global CO2 emissions, the industry recognised early on its role <strong>and</strong> responsibility for<br />

emission reductions. In 1999 ten <strong>of</strong> the world's leading cement producers combined<br />

efforts towards a more sustainable approach to cement production. Under the<br />

coordination <strong>of</strong> the World Business Council for Sustainable Development (WBCSD),<br />

these industry representatives started to invest in research, develop joint st<strong>and</strong>ards for<br />

emissions monitoring <strong>and</strong> reporting, <strong>and</strong> agreed on a technology roadmap for the<br />

reduction <strong>of</strong> the most hazardous emissions, including the halving <strong>of</strong> CO2 reductions<br />

until 2050. <strong>The</strong>ir efforts illustrate effectively, how an industry can decrease production<br />

cost while pursuing a socially desirable objective, thus strengthening the industry's<br />

licence to operate. In the next section, the characteristics <strong>of</strong> the industry are briefly<br />

summarised, before further analysing Holcim as a major global player.<br />

132 Cement is a hydraulic powder material, which reacts with water to produce strength-bearing<br />

lattices. Combined with aggregates <strong>and</strong> water, the result is concrete whose strength <strong>and</strong> durability<br />

make it invaluable for modern economies, <strong>and</strong> for which no adequate substitute exists to date.


Case Studies<br />

Figure 5-10: Cement production process <strong>and</strong> associated externalities 133<br />

5.3.1 Industry characteristics<br />

<strong>The</strong> cement industry is infrastructure-heavy <strong>and</strong> among the most capital-intensive<br />

industries <strong>of</strong> the world 134 . <strong>The</strong> average cost <strong>of</strong> a cement plant is usually above EUR<br />

150m per million tonnes <strong>of</strong> annual capacity, involving site-specific assets whose<br />

modifications are equally costly. <strong>The</strong>se significant sunk costs involve long pay-back<br />

periods, which explain the long-term nature <strong>of</strong> the industry. Furthermore, “the plants<br />

operate under conditions <strong>of</strong> high fixed costs <strong>and</strong> substantial increasing returns to scale”<br />

(McBride, 1983). As the sector is very energy-intensive, it depends on sufficient fuel<br />

supply - mostly in the form <strong>of</strong> gas <strong>and</strong> coal, electricity or, increasingly, alternative<br />

energy sources. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, labour intensity is low, due to the availability <strong>of</strong><br />

modern machinery <strong>and</strong> material h<strong>and</strong>ling.<br />

Similar to utilities, the cement industry produces a homogeneous product, which can<br />

be categorised into a number <strong>of</strong> cement classes, whose sub-products <strong>of</strong>fer little<br />

opportunities for differentiation between the producers. <strong>The</strong>refore, quality premiums<br />

133 WBCSD, n.d. ‘What is Cement?’. Retrieved February 15, 2010, from:<br />

www.wbcsdcement.org/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=69&Itemid=140.<br />

134<br />

Cf. CEMBUREAU, 'Cement industry - main characteristics'. Retrieved March 18, 2010, from:<br />

www.cembureau.eu/about-cement/cement-industry-main-characteristics.<br />

283


284<br />

Case Studies<br />

exist but are rather limited <strong>and</strong> the industry is rather focused on price, provided it is in<br />

competition with other producers. However, as <strong>of</strong>ten as not, the cement sector is<br />

characterised by regional oligopolies, because the product is heavy <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong><br />

transportation costs are significant. Usually the geographical range <strong>of</strong> a local cement<br />

producer is limited to a radius <strong>of</strong> 200-300 km 135 . <strong>The</strong>se limitations, combined with the<br />

industry’s reliance on the construction sector, mostly lead to a market-clustering,<br />

resulting in a collection <strong>of</strong> quasi-independent local geographic markets.<br />

In the industrialised part <strong>of</strong> the world, cement is considered a mature product. In<br />

Europe, for example, there are considerable country differences in the cement<br />

consumption per capita, depending on the evolution <strong>and</strong> structure <strong>of</strong> the construction<br />

sector. Since the latter closely follows the economic cycle, the cement industry equally<br />

depends on economic growth <strong>and</strong> is exposed to cyclical patterns <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>.<br />

<strong>The</strong> structure <strong>of</strong> the cement industry historically has been influenced by the two<br />

factors <strong>of</strong> high transportation costs <strong>and</strong> significant economies <strong>of</strong> scale in production<br />

(Newmark, 1998). Even though these industry characteristics would appear to limit the<br />

value <strong>of</strong> multinational presence (R. E. Caves, 1998; Ghemawat & Thomas, 2005), the<br />

cement <strong>and</strong> building materials industry has undergone a global consolidation process<br />

within the past three decades. From this ongoing process five major global players<br />

have emerged, each “with clearly identifiable national origins <strong>and</strong> controlled leading<br />

shares <strong>of</strong> their respective home markets” (Ghemawat & Thomas, 2008: 1981):<br />

Lafarge, Holcim, Cemex, HeidelbergCement, <strong>and</strong> Italcementi, whose size relations are<br />

shown in Table 5-7.<br />

Rank Company Net sales (EUR million)<br />

1 Lafarge 15'884<br />

2 Holcim 13'994<br />

3 HeidelbergCement 11'117<br />

4 Cemex 10'456<br />

5 Italcementi 5'006<br />

Table 5-7: Net sales volumes <strong>of</strong> top five cement producers (2009) 136<br />

135<br />

In cases, where bulk shipping is available this radius may be increased, since maritime<br />

transportation is significantly cheaper than overl<strong>and</strong> transport.<br />

136<br />

Company information.


Case Studies<br />

5.3.2 Swiss cement <strong>and</strong> building materials market<br />

<strong>The</strong> cement market in industrialised Switzerl<strong>and</strong> is a mature market with a highly<br />

developed infrastructure. This slow-growth market is vertically integrated <strong>and</strong><br />

dominated by three cement companies - Holcim, Jura Cement, <strong>and</strong> Ciments Vigier SA<br />

- which operate a total <strong>of</strong> six cement production plants. <strong>The</strong> production volume in<br />

2009 amounted to 4'333 million tonnes (cf. CemSuisse). <strong>The</strong> industry is partly<br />

vertically integrated <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> is dominated by 30 major customers who consume<br />

60% <strong>of</strong> the overall volume (Lurati, 2009).<br />

Due to the subordinate role <strong>of</strong> the Swiss cement market for Holcim we will not go into<br />

further detail on the country's market specificities.<br />

5.3.3 <strong>The</strong> case <strong>of</strong> Holcim<br />

As shown in Table 5-8, Holcim is the world's second largest cement <strong>and</strong> building<br />

materials company. It employs 81'500 people worldwide, with annual revenues <strong>of</strong><br />

CHF 21.1 billions (2009). In spite <strong>of</strong> its size, the company has retained an astonishing<br />

ability to react quickly, to take critical decisions towards the achievement <strong>of</strong> its<br />

economic goals, <strong>and</strong> to implement new processes or st<strong>and</strong>ards without delay. With the<br />

help <strong>of</strong> well-structured management systems <strong>and</strong> clear targets for all relevant corporate<br />

divisions, decisions can be taken locally <strong>and</strong> with no loss <strong>of</strong> time.<br />

Holcim has a clear pr<strong>of</strong>it orientation, but equally accepts its responsibility for the<br />

impact <strong>of</strong> its activities on its environment, stakeholders, <strong>and</strong> on the regional economy:<br />

<strong>The</strong> group is one <strong>of</strong> the most active companies with regard to corporate social<br />

responsibility <strong>and</strong> sustainability, <strong>and</strong> its pr<strong>of</strong>it margins demonstrate that socially<br />

responsible behaviour <strong>and</strong> economic success are no contradiction. Even in the difficult<br />

years <strong>of</strong> 2008 <strong>and</strong> 2009, where the industry contracted due to the economic crisis,<br />

Holcim managed to maintain an operating pr<strong>of</strong>it margin <strong>of</strong> slightly above 13%, which<br />

is only consistently surpassed by its larger competitor Lafarge (cf. Table 5-8).<br />

Immediate capacity adaptations, efficiency initiatives <strong>and</strong> other cost cutting programs<br />

allowed the company to make pr<strong>of</strong>its, although net sales shrank 7% in 2008,<br />

respectively 16% in 2009.<br />

285


286<br />

Rank Company 2007 2008 2009<br />

1 Lafarge 18.7% 18.6% 15.6%<br />

2 Holcim 18.6% 13.4% 13.2%<br />

3 HeidelbergCement 17.0% 15.1% 11.8%<br />

4 Cemex 13.7% 11.6% 8.0%<br />

5 Italcementi 10.2% 4.3% 4.8%<br />

Table 5-8: Operating pr<strong>of</strong>it margins <strong>of</strong> top five cement producers 137<br />

Case Studies<br />

History & organisation. Holcim was founded in 1912 - then named 'Aargauische<br />

Portl<strong>and</strong>cementfabrik Holderbank-Wildegg' - in the Swiss canton Aargau. It looks<br />

back on a long history <strong>of</strong> internationalisation, which started in the 1920s when Holcim<br />

began to invest selectively in Europe <strong>and</strong> overseas. From the very beginning, the firm's<br />

managers recognised the limited expansion opportunities in the domestic market,<br />

which remained one <strong>of</strong> the key drivers for its international growth. Today, Holcim is a<br />

global building materials group which operates in over 70 countries on all continents.<br />

Its core businesses include the manufacture <strong>and</strong> distribution <strong>of</strong> cement, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

production, processing <strong>and</strong> distribution <strong>of</strong> aggregates 138 , ready-mix concrete <strong>and</strong><br />

asphalt. Increasingly, it also <strong>of</strong>fers consulting, research, trading, engineering <strong>and</strong> other<br />

services. <strong>The</strong> business strategy is based on continuous growth in both, developed<br />

economies <strong>and</strong> emerging high-growth markets. Holcim's success factors include<br />

market-oriented structures, product innovations, skilled employees <strong>and</strong> efficient<br />

environmental management systems. Because it strictly focuses on value creation in<br />

the short- <strong>and</strong> longer-term, great importance is given to sustainable development at an<br />

economic, ecological <strong>and</strong> social level. Its engagement towards improving the<br />

sustainability <strong>of</strong> its business model has been acknowledged by the Dow Jones<br />

Sustainability Index, which has awarded Holcim as the industry leader for four<br />

consecutive between 2005 <strong>and</strong> 2008 139 .<br />

Holcim's leadership approach stresses the expertise <strong>of</strong> the local management. <strong>The</strong><br />

group’s management <strong>and</strong> line responsibility is organised by geographical regions.<br />

137 Company information.<br />

138<br />

I.e. crushed stone, gravel <strong>and</strong> s<strong>and</strong>.<br />

139<br />

In 2009, Holcim again received top scores with regard to its recycling strategy, its human capital<br />

development, its corporate citizenship approach <strong>and</strong> its engagement with stakeholders, but comes<br />

second after Panasonic Electric Works Co Ltd.


Case Studies<br />

Senior management is supported by efficient corporate staff units <strong>and</strong> management<br />

systems. Operative units are reporting to members <strong>of</strong> the board <strong>of</strong> management,<br />

supported by the country managers <strong>and</strong> corporate functional managers. With the help<br />

<strong>of</strong> these flat hierarchical structures <strong>and</strong> clearly defined divisions <strong>of</strong> responsibility at all<br />

levels, Holcim is able to remain agile in its responses to the market. To optimally<br />

employ <strong>and</strong> diffuse its accumulated knowledge, Holcim continuously trains <strong>and</strong><br />

promotes its key people <strong>and</strong> high potential employees. As a result,Holcim has a talent<br />

pool for systematic succession planning - on a country level, as well as on group level.<br />

In view <strong>of</strong> the significant risks inherent to the business, <strong>and</strong> the size <strong>of</strong> the company,<br />

Holcim's risk management puts special focus on the efficiency <strong>and</strong> efficacy <strong>of</strong> its<br />

internal control systems. <strong>The</strong>se include reliability <strong>and</strong> completeness checks <strong>of</strong> the<br />

financial <strong>and</strong> operative information, compliance with internal <strong>and</strong> external guidelines<br />

<strong>and</strong> legal st<strong>and</strong>ards, as well as audits for securing the group's working capital.<br />

Strategic orientation & geographical presence. According to the company's annual<br />

report 2009 (Holcim Ltd., 2010), its strategy is based on three pillars:<br />

(1) concentration on the core business,<br />

(2) geographical diversification, <strong>and</strong><br />

(3) balancing business responsibility between local <strong>and</strong> global leadership.<br />

This combination seemed to help Holcim to successfully manage through the recent<br />

economic turbulences. In addition, the group seeks to diversify its risks <strong>and</strong> to smooth<br />

out cyclical fluctuations through its broad geographical presence, which entails 70<br />

countries, 57 principal joint ventures <strong>and</strong> equity-consolidated companies, <strong>and</strong><br />

approximately 2'000 production facilities.<br />

Figure 5-11: Holcim's global presence (2009)<br />

287


288<br />

Case Studies<br />

In its sales portfolio, the importance <strong>of</strong> emerging markets is steadily increasing, adding<br />

up to 52.4% <strong>of</strong> overall net-sales in 2009. This strong presence in emerging markets<br />

entails also different kinds <strong>of</strong> responsibility, as compared to mature markets, which are<br />

further outlined in the subsequent section.<br />

Asia Pacific<br />

29%<br />

Africa &<br />

Middle East<br />

6%<br />

Latin America<br />

15%<br />

Europe<br />

34%<br />

North America<br />

16%<br />

Figure 5-12: Holcim's sales per region in percent (2009) 140<br />

Corporate philosophy. As reflected in its corporate philosophy, Holcim is aware <strong>of</strong><br />

the impact it has on the livelihoods <strong>of</strong> local populations where it operates, as well as<br />

the environmental impacts <strong>of</strong> its operations. Its vision therefore is “to provide<br />

foundations for society's future” (Holcim Ltd., 2004: 4), which is achieved through<br />

central strategies <strong>and</strong> by means <strong>of</strong> empowerment <strong>of</strong> the group companies, to enable<br />

“their autonomy <strong>and</strong> leveraging their local strengths to the benefit <strong>of</strong> all” (ibid.: 4). As<br />

its mission, the group foremost strives “to be the world’s most respected <strong>and</strong> attractive<br />

company in our industry – creating value for all our stakeholders” (ibid.: 5). <strong>The</strong>se<br />

core creeds translate, among others, into the following objectives:<br />

- to partner with the world’s best suppliers, in order to leverage opportunities <strong>and</strong> to<br />

deliver increased value for both, the group <strong>and</strong> its customers;<br />

- to continually demonstrate commitment to sustainable environmental performance,<br />

<strong>and</strong> to play a leading role in social responsibility within the company's sphere <strong>of</strong><br />

influence; <strong>and</strong><br />

- to maintain an active dialogue with governments, international organisations <strong>and</strong><br />

NGOs, <strong>and</strong> to be acknowledged as a valued <strong>and</strong> trusted partner.<br />

<strong>The</strong> group's philosophy <strong>and</strong> goals are reflected in its 'triple bottom line' - economic,<br />

social <strong>and</strong> environmental - which has been incorporated into its business strategy for<br />

140 Holcim Ltd, 2010a.


Case Studies<br />

years <strong>and</strong> guides its employees' decisions at all levels. By taking this holistic approach,<br />

Holcim is convinced it “can secure the company’s long-term success. <strong>The</strong> basis for<br />

this is an exceptional operational performance <strong>and</strong> a solid return on the capital<br />

invested” 141 .<br />

5.3.4 Holcim's location-fixity<br />

Being the producer <strong>of</strong> bulky <strong>and</strong> heavy products, which are created from locally<br />

sourced raw materials, Holcim is a prime example <strong>of</strong> a location-bound company<br />

outside the domain <strong>of</strong> the conventional utilities. As the company itself states, “natural<br />

resources are a precious commodity - our products are dependent on quarrying”<br />

(Holcim Ltd., 2009: 6). Consequently, Holcim's location-fixity is rooted in its l<strong>and</strong>,<br />

ins<strong>of</strong>ar as raw material reserves are concerned, <strong>and</strong> its buildings <strong>and</strong> installations,<br />

which are site-specific <strong>and</strong> which it writes <strong>of</strong>f over a period <strong>of</strong> 20-40 years (Holcim<br />

Ltd., 2010: 122). Table 5-9 provides an overview on Holcim's location dependence<br />

along the construct's characteristics, as specified in our research framework.<br />

Characteristic Applicable<br />

for Holcim<br />

Upstream<br />

Natural<br />

Resource<br />

Dependence<br />

Upstream<br />

Tangible<br />

Asset<br />

Dependence<br />

(continued next page)<br />

Comment<br />

~ For the production <strong>of</strong> cement, the company depends on clinker.<br />

High transportation costs usually suggest the co-location <strong>of</strong><br />

limestone quarrying, clinker production processes, <strong>and</strong> further<br />

processes for cement production (cf. interview N°7: 3).<br />

Equally, for the production <strong>of</strong> aggregates (i.e. granular materials<br />

such as s<strong>and</strong>, gravel, or crushed stone, which are essential<br />

ingredients in concrete) the firm's location-fixity bases on its<br />

dependence on a quarry, <strong>and</strong> the existence <strong>of</strong> the relevant<br />

concessions for mining <strong>and</strong> exploitation.<br />

However, all these raw-materials are widely available. For the<br />

cement industry, location-fixity comes with the decision for a<br />

location <strong>and</strong> the ensuing sunk cost investments (cf. interview N°9:<br />

6f; see next line).<br />

� Sunk cost investments in a cement plant usually amount to around<br />

EUR 150m per million tons <strong>of</strong> annual capacity (CEMBUREAU).<br />

Amortisation periods for an asset range from 20-40 years, but<br />

investment horizons are between 50-150 yrs. (cf. interview N°8: 2).<br />

141<br />

'Company pr<strong>of</strong>ile'. Retrieved March 15, from Holcim corporate website:<br />

http://www.holcim.com/index.php?id=4197.<br />

289


290<br />

Characteristic Applicable<br />

for Holcim<br />

Downstream<br />

Dependence<br />

on Market<br />

Proximity<br />

Ownership<br />

Dependence<br />

on Owners'<br />

Utility<br />

Function<br />

Comment<br />

Case Studies<br />

� Cement production depends on customer-proximity, due to high<br />

transportation costs <strong>and</strong> the commodity character <strong>of</strong> cement.<br />

Exceptions to the rule are production plants which are located close<br />

to maritime shipping terminals, thus being able to transport cement<br />

by water over longer distances at lower cost.<br />

� Holcim has developed from a family business. To today Thomas<br />

Schmidheiny, member <strong>of</strong> the founding family, owns more than 18%<br />

<strong>of</strong> the group's shares <strong>and</strong> is a member <strong>of</strong> the board <strong>of</strong> directors.<br />

However, Holcim essentially is a publicly traded firm with the<br />

majority <strong>of</strong> its shares freely floating. Thus, its business orientation<br />

is primarily pr<strong>of</strong>it-driven <strong>and</strong> there is no shareholder-related<br />

conflict <strong>of</strong> interest with regard to its geographical expansion.<br />

� fully applicable / ~ weakly applicable / � not applicable<br />

Table 5-9: <strong>Location</strong> dependence <strong>of</strong> Holcim by construct characteristics<br />

5.3.5 Holcim's environment - institutional exposure<br />

Producing cement has significant positive <strong>and</strong> negative impacts at a local level. <strong>The</strong><br />

impacts from quarrying <strong>and</strong> cement plants are large <strong>and</strong> visible to neighbouring<br />

stakeholders, leaving lasting impressions on the l<strong>and</strong>scape. <strong>The</strong>refore, expectations<br />

from various stakeholder groups are high <strong>and</strong> require sensitive h<strong>and</strong>ling <strong>of</strong> their<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>s, in order to maintain the licence to operate. <strong>The</strong> cement industry, including<br />

Holcim, has made its experiences with strained stakeholder relations <strong>and</strong> the possible<br />

impacts there<strong>of</strong>, ranging from long court battles, demonstrations <strong>of</strong> protest at the gates,<br />

boycotts, environmental damage, <strong>and</strong> facility closures (CSI, 2005).<br />

<strong>The</strong> Cement Sustainability Initiative (CSI, 2005: 36) 142 defines the industry's<br />

stakeholders as<br />

all individuals who see themselves as potentially affected by or who can impact<br />

cement operations at the local, national, or international scale. <strong>The</strong>se groups<br />

include, but are not limited to, neighbours, community organisations, nongovernmental<br />

organisations (NGO), contractors, academia, <strong>and</strong> suppliers.<br />

Apart from the local communities, particularly the regulatory bodies belong to the<br />

most involved stakeholders <strong>of</strong> the industry. <strong>The</strong> subsequent paragraphs provide an<br />

142<br />

CSI is a global association by 11 major cement producers for the pursuit <strong>of</strong> sustainable<br />

development, see also www.wbcsdcement.org/.


Case Studies<br />

overview on Holcim's exposure to the various stakeholders, using the stakeholder<br />

typology from our model, which includes the stakeholders as identified by CSI.<br />

<strong>Local</strong> community: exposure towards voting population; plant neighbours. With<br />

regard to local community exposure, differences exist between mature <strong>and</strong> emerging<br />

markets. Issues in mature markets usually revolve around the plant's various kinds <strong>of</strong><br />

emissions, its impacts on the local l<strong>and</strong>scape <strong>and</strong> operational sustainability (see also<br />

next paragraph). By contrast, the firm's cement plants in emerging markets <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

constitute a major factor in the local economies <strong>and</strong> are an important source for the<br />

local population's livelihood. Stakeholders in such environments have divergent sets <strong>of</strong><br />

expectations, leading to wholly different social responsibilities <strong>of</strong> the firm. An<br />

example <strong>of</strong> these differences is cited by Holcim's country manager in Azerbaijan<br />

(interview N°7: 8):<br />

For Azeri people … some aspects are more important than to people in the United<br />

States, for instance. In Azerbaijan, the neighbours <strong>of</strong> a cement plant have less<br />

environmental concerns, but they would like to see the company to be more involved<br />

in the education <strong>of</strong> their children or the development <strong>of</strong> infrastructure. … In<br />

contrast, people in the United States don't want to hear about a cement plant in<br />

their neighbourhood at all.<br />

Either way, the major impacts <strong>of</strong> cement plants on their neighbourhoods engender<br />

significant exposure to the local community.<br />

Civilian interest groups: exposure towards human rights, nature, <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong>scape<br />

conservation groups. Cement production causes disturbance to the l<strong>and</strong>scape, dust<br />

<strong>and</strong> noise, <strong>and</strong> disruption to local biodiversity from quarrying limestone. Not<br />

surprisingly, the industry is in the focus <strong>of</strong> many interest groups on all spatial scales.<br />

Examples for campaigns <strong>of</strong> global interest groups activities are Holcim's nomination<br />

for the 'Public Eye' award in 2008 to criticise employment practices <strong>of</strong> its subsidiary<br />

ACC in India, or a Greenpeace campaign in 2003 to fault the h<strong>and</strong>ling <strong>of</strong> an oil<br />

accident in Holcim's Lebanon operation. On a more regional level, exposure may arise<br />

with regard to ethnical or political conflicts, as in the case <strong>of</strong> Holcim's minority stake<br />

engagement in Guatemala. <strong>The</strong>re, in 2008 an organisation called 'Abogados de Maya'<br />

accused Holcim's local partner <strong>of</strong> violating the rights <strong>of</strong> the indigenous population.<br />

Customers: exposure due to business cycle dependence. Dem<strong>and</strong> for cement is<br />

closely connected with the volatile construction sector <strong>and</strong> varies regionally <strong>and</strong><br />

seasonally. Thus, the cement sector <strong>of</strong>ten struggles to have the right amount <strong>of</strong><br />

capacity in the right places at the right times. As a consequence, in times <strong>of</strong> downturns<br />

291


292<br />

Case Studies<br />

cement plants suffer from the combination <strong>of</strong> potential price-wars with the<br />

competition 143 <strong>and</strong> high fixed costs <strong>of</strong> their assets <strong>and</strong> plant operation. Marginal<br />

production costs rise rapidly in times <strong>of</strong> underutilisation <strong>of</strong> existing capacities. Other<br />

than that, no exposure to customers exists. In face <strong>of</strong> the <strong>of</strong>ten oligopolistic market<br />

structures in the cement industry, reality frequently shows an inverse dependence <strong>of</strong><br />

customers on the industry.<br />

Suppliers: exposure to strategic suppliers for uninterrupted kiln operation;<br />

exposure with regard to negative reputational spillovers. Holcim is interested in<br />

long-term relationships with its suppliers “to secure the most value-enhancing products<br />

<strong>and</strong> services” 144 . Due to its global presence <strong>and</strong> engagements in countries, where<br />

legislation <strong>and</strong> regulation are not very advanced, <strong>and</strong> where rule <strong>of</strong> law is not always<br />

prevailing, its exposure to suppliers mostly stems from reputational concerns. As a<br />

consequence, Holcim's sourcing needs to ensure that also its partners implement<br />

minimal st<strong>and</strong>ards with regard to working conditions, corruption, environmental<br />

practices <strong>and</strong> environmental impact. To guarantee a sustainable supply chain, the<br />

group therefore has developed a supplier qualification programme which includes<br />

local <strong>and</strong> global suppliers.<br />

With regard to resource supply, Holcim is in the process <strong>of</strong> increasing the use <strong>of</strong><br />

mineral components in its plants, in order to improve energy efficiency. <strong>The</strong>se changes<br />

also entail logistical challenges: “Sources <strong>of</strong> mineral components are <strong>of</strong>ten linked with<br />

other production processes remote from our production facilities. Thus, strategic<br />

sourcing <strong>and</strong> efficient logistics are required for long-term reliability <strong>of</strong> supply, <strong>and</strong><br />

strict quality assurance systems are critical to ensure the consistent quality <strong>of</strong> our<br />

products” (HGRS - CSR/SD Coordination, 2007: 2).<br />

Service partners: see also suppliers. Holcim sometimes outsources parts <strong>of</strong> its value<br />

chain, as for example the operation <strong>of</strong> quarries. Although Holcim is mainly involved<br />

as a purchaser <strong>of</strong> the end product, the public perceives the operation to be a part <strong>of</strong><br />

Holcim. Resulting exposures therefore are similar to those against (strategic) suppliers.<br />

143 According to Mabry (1998), empirical evidence shows that dem<strong>and</strong> for cement is relatively priceinelastic.<br />

Lower prices in economic downturns have only a redistributive character between competing<br />

firms, which is one <strong>of</strong> the reasons, why cement producers <strong>of</strong>ten are accused <strong>of</strong> collusion as means to<br />

avoid such deteriorations in price. <strong>The</strong> example <strong>of</strong> the recent economic crisis, which started in 2008,<br />

shows that cement majors suffer from pressure on prices due to weak construction markets. For<br />

Holcim, this pressure had an effect in 2009 particularly in some European markets.<br />

144<br />

'Customer <strong>and</strong> supplier relations'. Retrieved July 20, 2010, from Holcim corporate website:<br />

www.holcim.com/index.php?id=4338&L=1.


Case Studies<br />

Employees: labour issues, strikes, sabotage, external job market exposure. <strong>The</strong><br />

cement industry has a long history <strong>of</strong> labour issues with its employees <strong>and</strong> trade<br />

unions. For various reasons, ranging from wage-discontentment, health <strong>and</strong> safety<br />

concerns, general labour conditions, to political protests, cement plants are sometimes<br />

exposed to momentary plant shut-downs due to employee action. Although Holcim<br />

generally maintains good relations with its workforce <strong>and</strong> has a reputation as a socially<br />

responsible employer, it occasionally is entangled in adverse firm-employee<br />

interactions. Recent examples include a row with workers in the Philippines on work<br />

contracts <strong>and</strong> pay increases, or worker protests in Spain, due to an announced plant<br />

closure. Apart from costs incurred through strikes, tense labour relations can also<br />

result in reputational spillovers.<br />

Shareholder: none. Since Holcim is a listed company with the majority <strong>of</strong> its shares<br />

free floating, there is no major exposure to its shareholders in respect <strong>of</strong> locationdependence<br />

<strong>and</strong> related conflicts <strong>of</strong> interest. Holcim has a clear pr<strong>of</strong>it orientation with<br />

a strong emphasis on ethical business conduct <strong>and</strong> sustainability.<br />

Government, regulator, politics: exposure due to legal complexity <strong>of</strong> industry<br />

regulation. Over the past decades, industry regulation <strong>and</strong> the complexity <strong>of</strong> legal<br />

procedures, particularly for new projects, have risen significantly. On the one h<strong>and</strong>, the<br />

number <strong>of</strong> parties being involved in permitting processes has increased. On the other<br />

h<strong>and</strong>, there are a large number <strong>of</strong> relevant regulations <strong>and</strong> regulatory bodies. To run<br />

through these processes needs time, involves costs <strong>and</strong> entails procedural uncertainty.<br />

Furthermore, societal trends <strong>and</strong> environmental awareness increase uncertainty in<br />

respect <strong>of</strong> production methods. As a result, the plants - once a technology is chosen -<br />

experience a lock-in situation, in which it becomes difficult to obtain approval for<br />

adaptations. Technological developments, for example, have facilitated the efficient<br />

use <strong>of</strong> waste from other industries as alternative fuels or raw materials (AFR) in<br />

cement production. In its endeavours to reduce CO2 emissions, but also to decrease its<br />

fossil fuel costs, Holcim has invested in research for the safe use <strong>of</strong> these AFR 145 .<br />

Between 1990 <strong>and</strong> 2008 Holcim's share <strong>of</strong> alternative fuels for the production <strong>of</strong><br />

thermal energy has risen from 3.7% to 12.2%. However, these AFR include materials<br />

such as scrap tires, plastics, solvents, impregnated sawdust, <strong>and</strong> other materials<br />

145 Between 2003 <strong>and</strong> 2008 Holcim was engaged in a strategic partnership with the German Agency<br />

for Technical Cooperation (GTZ) in order to improve waste management. <strong>The</strong> partnering research<br />

resulted in st<strong>and</strong>ards for the safe incineration <strong>of</strong> waste, including toxic waste, which is particularly<br />

valuable to close gaps in the legislation <strong>of</strong> selected developing countries.<br />

293


294<br />

Case Studies<br />

potentially resulting in dangerous emissions. Thus, the bias between Holcim's vision<br />

for the safe use <strong>of</strong> AFR <strong>and</strong> societal opposition results in regulatory uncertainty, which<br />

is an example <strong>of</strong> the firm's exposure to public stakeholders.<br />

Besides, regulatory exposure depends on a country's institutional <strong>and</strong> cultural set-up.<br />

Referring once more to the example <strong>of</strong> Azerbaijan, the most important stakeholder to<br />

Holcim is the government. Importantly, due to cultural factors, relational management<br />

capabilities concerning public authorities are more important than in Western<br />

countries. If a firm neglects this circumstance, it may evoke administrative discretion,<br />

possibly negatively affecting permitting processes, approval <strong>of</strong> new product st<strong>and</strong>ards,<br />

or provoking regulatory fining, etc. In respect <strong>of</strong> permitting, for example, in Western<br />

Europe it is sufficient to follow the procedure as defined by the regulator <strong>and</strong> the<br />

respective laws. Although these processes equally are defined in Azerbaijan, the<br />

material fulfilling <strong>of</strong> all criteria in itself will not grant procedural progress, because<br />

“you really have to know the people, personally see them, explain your request, <strong>and</strong><br />

discuss with them the sequence <strong>of</strong> steps to finally obtain a permit” (interview N°7: 10).<br />

5.3.6 Holcim's legitimisation capabilities<br />

As a consequence <strong>of</strong> its exposure, Holcim has long recognised the importance <strong>of</strong> local<br />

embedding <strong>and</strong> sustainable relationship building with its key stakeholders. Holcim<br />

also acknowledges that its social engagement is not altruistic, but rather strategic in<br />

nature. <strong>The</strong> group<br />

sees an active commitment to social responsibility <strong>and</strong> a continuous dialogue with<br />

its stakeholder groups as essential preconditions for a stable corporate <strong>and</strong><br />

business environment. This is why Holcim supports projects in the fields <strong>of</strong><br />

education <strong>and</strong> training, infrastructure <strong>and</strong> sustainable community development.<br />

(Holcim Ltd., 2010: 47)<br />

Equally the commitment to sustainable development constitutes a core component <strong>of</strong><br />

its corporate success (ibid.). Thus, as the basis <strong>of</strong> its 'licence to operate', Holcim has<br />

defined the following priority issues: occupational health <strong>and</strong> safety; climate <strong>and</strong><br />

energy; sustainable products <strong>and</strong> services; sustainable construction; resources<br />

conservation; community involvement; <strong>and</strong> stakeholder engagement. In the following<br />

passages we will describe Holcim's capabilities for structural <strong>and</strong> relational<br />

embedding, along the dimensions <strong>of</strong> our research framework.<br />

Capabilities towards structural local embedding. Due to the significant effects <strong>of</strong><br />

its plants on local communities, particularly at the less developed locations where it


Case Studies<br />

operates, Holcim accepts its responsibility to support these communities in various<br />

economically important ways.<br />

(a) value share remaining in region. According to Holcim's factsheet on community<br />

involvement, “being a good neighbour entails not only limiting environmental impacts,<br />

but also working with our stakeholders to help improve their quality <strong>of</strong> life” (Holcim<br />

Ltd, 2007a: 1). <strong>The</strong>refore, Holcim attaches great importance to a structured approach<br />

in community engagement, including the provision <strong>of</strong> financial means for related<br />

projects. It describes its approach to local engagement as follows (2009b: 7):<br />

Holcim has a longst<strong>and</strong>ing commitment to the communities where our facilities are<br />

located. Frequently the biggest local employer, we recognise our social<br />

responsibility. Our Group companies promote education <strong>and</strong> training, sustainable<br />

community development <strong>and</strong> improvements in local infrastructure. With innovative<br />

concepts, technical support, easy access to construction materials <strong>and</strong> sources <strong>of</strong><br />

funding, Holcim gives larger sections <strong>of</strong> the population an opportunity to carry out<br />

their own building projects.<br />

<strong>The</strong> firm sources an average <strong>of</strong> 66% <strong>of</strong> its total procurement spend locally, with<br />

around 75% <strong>of</strong> its suppliers being local. In addition, taxes <strong>and</strong> wages significantly<br />

contribute to the local communities 146 . Importantly, these 'regular' value contributions<br />

are complemented by Holcim's community spending, which amounts to one percent <strong>of</strong><br />

its consolidated pr<strong>of</strong>it before taxes. In 2009, the company spent CHF 37m on social<br />

projects worldwide, reaching around three million beneficiaries. Table 5-10 provides<br />

an overview on the categories <strong>of</strong> Holcim's investments in community projects.<br />

Category mCHF (%)<br />

Community development projects 6.7 18<br />

Education projects 7.0 19<br />

Infrastructure community projects 6.3 17<br />

Donation <strong>and</strong> charity 9.6 26<br />

CSR overhead 5.2 14<br />

Others 2.2 6<br />

Total 37.0 100<br />

Table 5-10: Holcim's community spending per category (2009) 147<br />

146 Overall, taxes amount to 4.5% <strong>and</strong> wages to 16.8% <strong>of</strong> net sales on the basis <strong>of</strong> its 2007 figures.<br />

147 Holcim Ltd., 2010: 47.<br />

295


296<br />

Case Studies<br />

Holcim’s community strategy is based on the development <strong>of</strong> human capacity. Some<br />

<strong>of</strong> the group's most successful community development projects have already been<br />

introduced in chapter four. <strong>The</strong>se examples can be complemented with other highimpact<br />

projects:<br />

- India - various locations. With the mission to energise, involve <strong>and</strong> enable<br />

communities to realise their potential, Ambuja Cement Foundation (ACF) currently<br />

works with 670 villages in ten Indian States. For its activities it has an annual<br />

budget <strong>of</strong> CHF 11m, <strong>of</strong> which half comes directly from Ambuja Cements - a<br />

subsidiary <strong>of</strong> the Holcim group - <strong>and</strong> the other half from the local government <strong>and</strong><br />

donor agencies. In villages around Ambuja Cement's 148 Kodinar plant, for example,<br />

it has established self-help groups that enable women to acquire new skills <strong>and</strong> to<br />

access micro-credit opportunities.<br />

- Vietnam - various locations. In the volunteer project Green Summer, run by the Ho<br />

Chi Minh City University <strong>of</strong> Technology, Holcim provides cement <strong>and</strong> cement<br />

know-how to the project participants. Thus, they are enabled to build rural<br />

pathways, rural bridges, low-cost houses <strong>and</strong> cultural centres. Further support from<br />

Holcim comes in the form <strong>of</strong> a kindergarten, built in the area <strong>of</strong> Green Summer's<br />

operations. Holcim aims to educate the leaders <strong>of</strong> the construction teams, in order<br />

to disseminate cement-related technical know-how <strong>and</strong> to raise their level <strong>of</strong> safety<br />

awareness.<br />

- Colombia - Nobsa, Iza <strong>and</strong> Tibasosa. In 2005, Holcim Colombia founded a project<br />

to support income generation for local farmers by creating the agricultural <strong>and</strong><br />

commercial association AGRONIT. Its goal is to ensure higher pr<strong>of</strong>its within the<br />

rural economy by improving the production conditions <strong>and</strong> by increasing the local<br />

knowledge <strong>of</strong> marketing tools. Thus, the farmers are encouraged to directly sell on<br />

the market <strong>and</strong> to better commercialise their products. Through analysis <strong>of</strong> the<br />

environmental, social <strong>and</strong> economic conditions in the region <strong>and</strong> the development<br />

<strong>of</strong> alternative solutions, AGRONIT is able to build capacity in the rural sector.<br />

Sometimes, also small projects have an enduring impact on the local population's firm<br />

acceptance. In Kosovo, for example, Holcim restored the central power line in a<br />

village, which used to break down frequently, leaving the inhabitants without power.<br />

Besides, it provided the building materials <strong>and</strong> the workers to renew water <strong>and</strong> sewer<br />

pipes, thus substantially improving the life <strong>of</strong> plant neighbours (cf. interview N°8: 10).<br />

148 Since 2008, Ambuja Cements is a fully consolidated subsidiary <strong>of</strong> the Holcim Group.


Case Studies<br />

Overall, Holcim's experiences with financial <strong>and</strong> capacity-building engagements are<br />

fruitful. <strong>The</strong> interviewed firm representatives believe that the value share thus returned<br />

to the region contributes to Holcim's organisational legitimacy <strong>and</strong> strategically<br />

contributes to its sustained pr<strong>of</strong>itability, e.g. by strengthening employee <strong>and</strong> customer<br />

loyalty. In some cases, its capacity-building activities even contribute to the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> new businesses, as has been demonstrated with the Mi Casa initiative<br />

in Mexico.<br />

(b) mutual lock-in between the firm <strong>and</strong> its major stakeholders. In contrast to utilities<br />

or public infrastructure, the cement industry - albeit economically important - does not<br />

necessarily play a strategic role for national economies. <strong>The</strong>refore, the issue <strong>of</strong> mutual<br />

lock-in as a protection is essential, but considerably more difficult to achieve<br />

compared to - for example - state-owned Axpo. In respect <strong>of</strong> its institutional exposure<br />

to public stakeholders, Holcim needs to secure a mutual lock-in during the preoperational<br />

negotiation phase, particularly by ensuring a long concession period <strong>and</strong><br />

favourable key terms <strong>of</strong> quarrying (e.g. conditions, annual volumes, etc.). Apart from<br />

the contractual agreement, investment protection also depends on the country’s legal<br />

<strong>and</strong> regulatory stability. To attain a further dimension <strong>of</strong> protection in its operational<br />

phase, Holcim thus selectively nominates local representatives <strong>and</strong> influential persons<br />

to the boards <strong>of</strong> its subsidiaries in order to support it in all kinds <strong>of</strong> topics.<br />

(c) internal governance. Corporate governance at Holcim entails established<br />

management processes, the organisation <strong>and</strong> monitoring <strong>of</strong> the highest corporate<br />

management levels, the definition <strong>of</strong> business policy principles, as well as internal <strong>and</strong><br />

external control mechanisms. It “is the precondition for the Group’s credibility <strong>and</strong><br />

good reputation <strong>and</strong> strengthens confidence among investors, business partners,<br />

employees <strong>and</strong> the public at large” (Holcim Ltd., 2010: 25). Holcim's vulnerability as<br />

a global business major, the nature <strong>of</strong> its business <strong>and</strong> market structures, but also its<br />

long-term dependence on the locations where it operates contribute to the high<br />

corporate awareness on the issue. In the company brochure Holcim at a Glance, it<br />

therefore states (Holcim Ltd., 2009: 3):<br />

Holcim strives to be a valued <strong>and</strong> reliable partner for all stakeholder groups as well<br />

as the most respected <strong>and</strong> attractive company in the building materials industry.<br />

Our strict Corporate Governance st<strong>and</strong>ards make a major contribution to achieving<br />

this goal.<br />

In its CSR Report 2007, the group further states (Holcim Ltd., 2008: 4):<br />

297


298<br />

Case Studies<br />

At Holcim, we recognise the importance <strong>of</strong> operating with integrity <strong>and</strong> apply high<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>of</strong> corporate governance in the conduct <strong>of</strong> our business. By<br />

demonstrating responsible <strong>and</strong> transparent leadership <strong>and</strong> management, we earn<br />

the trust <strong>of</strong> our stakeholders, which is essential to achieving long-term success.<br />

By setting high st<strong>and</strong>ards, Holcim fosters responsible <strong>and</strong> transparent company<br />

leadership, <strong>and</strong> gears its management towards long-term success <strong>and</strong> sustainable value<br />

creation. Part <strong>of</strong> these st<strong>and</strong>ards is the Holcim Compliance Policy with which the<br />

group sets the rules for all employees. <strong>The</strong>rein, Holcim defines the st<strong>and</strong>ards for<br />

compliance with external laws <strong>and</strong> regulations, as well as with company-wide internal<br />

policies, following a zero tolerance approach.<br />

In order to strengthen its local embedding <strong>and</strong> trust-building, Holcim established an<br />

environmental assessment system, the Plant Emission Pr<strong>of</strong>iles (PEP). With the help <strong>of</strong><br />

this tool it is able to monitor its performance on three operational levels: individual<br />

plant performance assessment, group company assessment, <strong>and</strong> corporate<br />

consolidation <strong>of</strong> plant performance worldwide. <strong>The</strong> monitoring <strong>of</strong> its plant<br />

externalities includes the continuous tracking <strong>of</strong> dust, nitrogen oxides, sulphur dioxide<br />

<strong>and</strong> volatile organic compounds, <strong>and</strong> at least an annual measuring <strong>of</strong> heavy metals,<br />

dioxins/furans, hydrogen chloride, benzene <strong>and</strong> ammonia. Its atmospheric plantemissions<br />

are monitored along the specifications <strong>of</strong> its Emission Monitoring <strong>and</strong><br />

Reporting (EMR). EMR is an internally developed corporate st<strong>and</strong>ard in order to<br />

globally establish a strict unified approach to emissions monitoring. This measure was<br />

necessary due to the considerable differences in regulatory st<strong>and</strong>ards between the<br />

countries where it operates. Overall, Holcim uses the monitoring data for its<br />

environmental management, regulatory compliance, <strong>and</strong> for the assessment <strong>of</strong> its<br />

performance. <strong>The</strong>se evaluations serve as inputs for the development <strong>of</strong> both, individual<br />

<strong>and</strong> integrated performance indicators for plant-specific environmental scorecards.<br />

Particularly in respect <strong>of</strong> its increased use <strong>of</strong> AFR thermal energy, Holcim is aware<br />

that it needs to provide its stakeholders with objective information on its plants'<br />

emissions. By measuring <strong>and</strong> publishing these results, Holcim stresses its commitment<br />

to continuously improve environmental performance.<br />

Capabilities towards relational local embedding. As aforementioned, local<br />

stakeholders' needs may differ significantly, depending on the operation's location, the<br />

cultural context <strong>and</strong> the economic maturity <strong>of</strong> the local environment. Recognising that<br />

it “need[s] to balance a systematic approach to engagement Group-wide with<br />

addressing local stakeholder needs <strong>and</strong> aspirations” (Holcim Ltd, 2007b: 2), Holcim


Case Studies<br />

has developed a stakeholder mapping process to assess those needs. Thus, it hopes to<br />

allocate the available financial means in order to maximise beneficiaries' utility. To<br />

remain focused, Holcim regularly performs an SD [sustainable development]<br />

materiality review, wherein it contrasts the internally identified key issues with<br />

feedback from its local stakeholders, thus validating its priorities. In this process, the<br />

firm involves its stakeholders in the determination <strong>of</strong> relevant issues <strong>and</strong> provides<br />

them with an underst<strong>and</strong>ing how these issues are prioritised, while <strong>of</strong>fering the<br />

possibility to discuss <strong>and</strong> challenge them if necessary.<br />

In addition, more than half <strong>of</strong> the group companies have validated their most important<br />

social projects on the basis <strong>of</strong> a Social Engagement Scorecard. Thus, Holcim aims to<br />

ensure that the projects effectively contribute to the group’s objectives, while at the<br />

same time improving the quality <strong>of</strong> life <strong>of</strong> the local population.<br />

(a) relational capabilities. Because the cement industry is very visible wherever there<br />

are plant operations, firms cannot hide from their social responsibility. Having<br />

understood the importance <strong>of</strong> being positively integrated in its host communities,<br />

Holcim recognises “that earning <strong>and</strong> keeping the trust <strong>and</strong> respect <strong>of</strong> our stakeholders,<br />

through strong SD performance, is not only a prerequisite for our license to operate,<br />

but will fundamentally strengthen our business” (Holcim Ltd, 2007b: 1). To foster the<br />

accumulation <strong>of</strong> goodwill trust, Holcim's activities toward relational embedding<br />

include:<br />

- the establishment <strong>of</strong> Community Advisory Panels (CAP), which involve<br />

representatives <strong>of</strong> interest groups, the local administration, etc.;<br />

- the exchange with other local organisations, such as the fire <strong>and</strong> rescue service,<br />

youth <strong>and</strong> children's organisations, schools, women's organisations, local<br />

NGOs, local authorities (cf. interview N°9: 5);<br />

- the publishing <strong>of</strong> environmental performance results (see also p.297);<br />

- periodical open plant days, which serve to inform the local community on the<br />

firm's activities, cement production processes, <strong>and</strong> other relevant issues;<br />

- local festivals, to provide the community with further opportunities to get in<br />

touch with the firm;<br />

- local sponsoring activities;<br />

- restoration projects, such as the renaturation <strong>and</strong> conversion <strong>of</strong> quarries into<br />

parks, public courses, educational walks, etc.; <strong>and</strong><br />

- pollution prevention initiatives.<br />

299


300<br />

Case Studies<br />

By seriously demonstrating that the concerns <strong>of</strong> the local stakeholders are important to<br />

the firm, Holcim is able to build strong relationships with its communities <strong>and</strong> the<br />

regulator, which improves both, the plant's performance <strong>and</strong> the local living<br />

conditions. While less than a decade ago Holcim followed a rather paternalistic<br />

approach towards 'doing good' (cf. interview N°9: 4), today the group's stakeholder<br />

involvement is fundamentally participative, with a focus on sustainable livelihood. <strong>The</strong><br />

use <strong>of</strong> CAPs, for example, led to remarkable results in overcoming tensions <strong>and</strong><br />

finding win-win solutions with affected local parties, <strong>and</strong> in the overall improvement<br />

<strong>of</strong> stakeholder relations. <strong>The</strong> positive effects <strong>of</strong> such panels are exemplified at the case<br />

<strong>of</strong> Holcim (US) Inc.'s Holly Hill plant, which initiated a CAP under difficult<br />

circumstances. As the plant failed to comply with emission st<strong>and</strong>ards in the 1990s 149 ,<br />

its organisational legitimacy <strong>and</strong> the local public's trust in its operation consequently<br />

suffered. Thus, the establishment <strong>of</strong> a CAP was seen as a chance to start rebuilding<br />

constructive relations with the local stakeholders. Today, the CAP has become an<br />

essential institution to inform the local managers on the community's concerns <strong>and</strong> to<br />

provide a reality check for the firm's business development plans. In the meantime, the<br />

members <strong>of</strong> the panel have developed into ambassadors for the plant, who in the<br />

beginning <strong>of</strong> 2000 even helped to create community support for a proposed plant<br />

expansion (CSI, 2005: 37). Holly Hill plant's exemplary community outreach has been<br />

recognised through an award by the US Portl<strong>and</strong> Cement Association (PCA) <strong>and</strong> by<br />

Cement Americas in 2008.<br />

Another best practice example for community relationship management can be found<br />

at Holcim Switzerl<strong>and</strong>. In its Sustainability Report 2005-2007 the unit states (Holcim<br />

(Schweiz) AG, 2008: 16):<br />

Each cement plant informs the local council on ongoing developments <strong>and</strong><br />

activities at least annually. <strong>The</strong> plant managers communicate directly with the<br />

concerned local councillor <strong>and</strong> cultivate their partnership with the local<br />

administration. Thus, both sides have the possibility to express their needs <strong>and</strong><br />

concerns openly.<br />

How to practice such community capacity building is exemplarily demonstrated at the<br />

Swiss Siggenthal plant. In the course <strong>of</strong> the 1990s, the plant gradually increased the<br />

use <strong>of</strong> AFR. <strong>The</strong>se alterations in production methods <strong>and</strong> the increased environmental<br />

awareness <strong>of</strong> the local population resulted in new needs for communicating <strong>and</strong><br />

149 In 1993, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) fined Holly Hill Plant for failing to comply<br />

with air emission st<strong>and</strong>ards.


Case Studies<br />

interacting with the local stakeholders. <strong>The</strong>refore, in the past decade Siggenthal's plant<br />

management heavily invested in the relationship-building with its host community.<br />

Through an intensification <strong>of</strong> stakeholder involvement, <strong>and</strong> repeated incorporation <strong>of</strong><br />

stakeholders' opinions, the plant enjoys broad backing among its neighbours, despite<br />

its being unusually closely located to the village. Its 'licence to operate' is further<br />

reinforced by the plant manager's skills for relationship management (cf. interview<br />

N°9: 2). <strong>The</strong> plant's local legitimisation activities, among others, include:<br />

- regular exchange with members <strong>of</strong> the CAP;<br />

- publication <strong>of</strong> a plant journal, informing the community on news <strong>and</strong> activities;<br />

- annual publication <strong>of</strong> plant emission pr<strong>of</strong>ile (PEP) results;<br />

- a makeover <strong>of</strong> the plant's cement silo façade with the winning picture <strong>of</strong> a local<br />

school competition “as a symbol <strong>of</strong> our plant's close bonds with its local<br />

community” 150 ; <strong>and</strong><br />

- various sponsoring activities.<br />

(b) reputation-building capabilities. Apart from its community involvement activities,<br />

which Holcim sees “as a way to … improve our reputation” (Holcim Ltd, 2007a: 2),<br />

Holcim engages in various strategic partnerships, which also serve its reputation <strong>and</strong><br />

increase its credibility. One <strong>of</strong> its partners is the German Agency for Technical<br />

Cooperation (GTZ), with whom it formed a strategic alliance between 2003 <strong>and</strong> 2009<br />

to improve waste management in developing <strong>and</strong> transition countries. <strong>The</strong> results <strong>of</strong><br />

the joint research led to a better underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the effects <strong>of</strong> co-processing, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

optimisation there<strong>of</strong>. Even after the expiry <strong>of</strong> the alliance, Holcim <strong>and</strong> GTZ continue<br />

to work together, fostering knowledge dissemination <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong>fering training courses in<br />

co-processing. Consequently, Holcim is able to relate its best practice st<strong>and</strong>ards in coprocessing<br />

to a credible independent source, which increases the method's <strong>and</strong> the<br />

firm's legitimacy. Furthermore, GTZ's conclusions on the basis <strong>of</strong> its scientifically<br />

sound assessments help to reduce uncertainty <strong>and</strong> to alleviate communities'<br />

reservations. As a responsible corporate citizen, Holcim not only applies these<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ards worldwide, but also actively helps to close gaps in some countries'<br />

legislation.<br />

Another organisation with which Holcim is partnering is concerned with the<br />

biodiversity in the surroundings <strong>of</strong> quarries. In 2007, Holcim signed an agreement for<br />

a three-year programme with the International Union for Conservation <strong>of</strong> Nature<br />

(IUCN), focusing on the management <strong>of</strong> ecosystems at Holcim’s sites. <strong>The</strong><br />

150 Remo Bernasconi, Holcim's Siggenthal plant manager, in a Holcim press release, June 08, 2005.<br />

301


302<br />

Case Studies<br />

programme includes the monitoring <strong>of</strong> Holcim's practices through a committee <strong>of</strong><br />

independent experts, in order to increase its credibility. At the end <strong>of</strong> the cooperation,<br />

Holcim will have developed a biodiversity strategy <strong>and</strong> a biodiversity management<br />

system, for which the exchanges with IUCN <strong>and</strong> the monitoring results form the basis<br />

(Holcim Ltd., 2010).<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the more recent engagements <strong>of</strong> Holcim is its membership in the support group<br />

<strong>of</strong> the International Red Cross (ICRC) to help the latter's field activities. In this longterm<br />

agreement, Holcim will fund humanitarian projects as part <strong>of</strong> its commitment to<br />

sustainable development 151 .<br />

Importantly, Holcim is also the recipient <strong>of</strong> a number <strong>of</strong> prestigious awards for its<br />

social <strong>and</strong> environmental engagements, which foster its reputation. Between 2005 <strong>and</strong><br />

2008, Holcim has been named Leader <strong>of</strong> the Industry in the Dow Jones Sustainability<br />

Index, as the company with the best sustainability performance in the building<br />

materials industry. Furthermore, in 2009 alone Holcim received 90 awards 152 , where<strong>of</strong><br />

- mostly on a national level - 13 awards were for its social activities, 35 for its<br />

environmental engagement, <strong>and</strong> 31 for its occupational health achievements. All <strong>of</strong><br />

these are valuable signals for the communities, where Holcim is present or where it<br />

intends to build a presence in the future.<br />

(c) capabilities to adapt to the local environment. One <strong>of</strong> Holcim's strategic pillars is<br />

the balancing <strong>of</strong> business responsibility between local <strong>and</strong> global leadership. This<br />

includes Holcim's ability to identify the relevant local characteristics, to skilfully use<br />

the local strengths, <strong>and</strong> to work with the local culture. For Holcim's country manager<br />

in Azerbaijan “local embeddedness means first <strong>of</strong> all, that you have to be aware <strong>of</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

respect the local culture. … You have to underst<strong>and</strong> the local conditions, in order to<br />

set the priorities right <strong>and</strong> to build up the strategy accordingly” (interview N°7: 8).<br />

Furthermore, in his view (interview N°7: 2)<br />

Holcim is a player which does not want to change the culture <strong>of</strong> the local company,<br />

where it is present. Maybe this has to do with the Swiss culture - in any case it is a<br />

success factor. <strong>The</strong>re are not many people delegated from the headquarters to the<br />

various countries. … <strong>The</strong>y try to adapt the Holcim culture to the local culture, not<br />

the other way round - a very positive factor.<br />

151<br />

'Holcim supports ICRC field activities'. Retrieved January 28, 2010, from ICRD corporate website:<br />

www.icrc.org/eng/resources/documents/news-release/private-sector-relations-news-280110.htm.<br />

152<br />

'Awards 2009'. Retrieved April 4, 2010, from Holcim corporate website:<br />

www.holcim.com/holcimcms/uploads/CORP/Awards_SD_2009.pdf.


Case Studies<br />

This cultural sensitivity <strong>and</strong> willingness to de-centrally adapt to local ways<br />

differentiates the Holcim from other major cement firms, such as for example Lafarge<br />

which is more centrally organised. Holcim's local approach is reinforced through a<br />

collaborative attitude, whereby stakeholders are perceived as partners, that need to be<br />

integrated in its decision-making process in order to develop innovative pr<strong>of</strong>essional<br />

solutions (Holcim Ltd., 2004).<br />

5.3.7 Value creation<br />

Holcim's long-term success grounds on a clear product strategy, centring on the<br />

production <strong>and</strong> distribution <strong>of</strong> cement <strong>and</strong> aggregates. Its investment activities <strong>and</strong><br />

value creation focalise on the processing <strong>of</strong> natural resources. As observed earlier,<br />

these activities are highly capital-intensive <strong>and</strong> tie up assets over long periods (Holcim<br />

Ltd., 2010). Consequently, Holcim has developed a characteristic approach to value<br />

creation, which is illustrated in Figure 5-13.<br />

Figure 5-13: Holcim's pillars <strong>of</strong> value creation 153<br />

<strong>The</strong> following passages will elucidate how Holcim sets out to implement its value<br />

approach. <strong>The</strong>y will elaborate more closely the group's various fields <strong>of</strong> value creation<br />

from a (1) single-site perspective on the local level, as well as from a (2) multi-site<br />

perspective.<br />

(1) Single-site perspective. On the basis <strong>of</strong> our empirical insights, we conclude that<br />

Holcim's subsidiaries successfully derive value from the careful fostering <strong>of</strong> their<br />

external legitimacy <strong>and</strong> their 'licence to operate'. By consciously deploying their<br />

153 Holcim Ltd, 2010a: 17.<br />

303


304<br />

Case Studies<br />

embedding capabilities, the subsidiaries are able to accumulate goodwill stocks, which<br />

contribute to value creation by<br />

- attracting qualified employees <strong>and</strong> increasing employee retention from the<br />

reputation as good employer, thus lowering transaction costs <strong>and</strong> exploiting<br />

economies <strong>of</strong> experience;<br />

- benefiting from good relations <strong>and</strong> high credibility with local banks, resulting in<br />

better financing opportunities, more strategic options, <strong>and</strong> lower transaction<br />

costs;<br />

- increasing organisational legitimacy <strong>and</strong> local support for new projects,<br />

reinforced by the subsidiaries' high acceptance with the local banks (cf.<br />

interview N°11: 8); <strong>and</strong><br />

- decreasing the risks 154 related to institutional exposure, resulting in a better<br />

protection <strong>of</strong> sunk cost investments (cf. interview N°9: 5).<br />

Particularly in Holcim's endeavours to reduce its reliance on fossil fuels through new<br />

production technologies, trust <strong>and</strong> firm credibility are key factors for success. In<br />

respect <strong>of</strong> AFR <strong>and</strong> co-processing, for example, local populations usually are<br />

concerned about emissions <strong>and</strong> potential impacts on health <strong>and</strong> environment. Only<br />

with a credible firm reputation, Holcim's arguments may have the legitimacy to reduce<br />

fears <strong>of</strong> directly affected stakeholders. Thus, its embedding capabilities ultimately<br />

create strategic options for its future development which might not be available to<br />

players with less legitimacy.<br />

Furthermore, embedding capabilities are also effective for the erection <strong>of</strong> protective<br />

mobility barriers, e.g. by using them as a means for competitor differentiation 155 . In<br />

most <strong>of</strong> its markets Holcim is in direct competition with other cement producers. With<br />

its embedding activities, <strong>and</strong> the resulting value added for the local stakeholders,<br />

Holcim <strong>of</strong>ten sets itself apart from other cement producers. Particularly with regard to<br />

business development, Holcim's accumulated stakeholder goodwill sometimes<br />

positively influences the probability <strong>of</strong> successful implementation, thus creating<br />

strategic options for future development. In Azerbaijan, for example, Holcim's country<br />

manager has been approached by a number <strong>of</strong> entrepreneurs <strong>and</strong> representatives <strong>of</strong><br />

154<br />

This observation applies to Holcim's fully consolidated subsidiaries. In its minority-engagements,<br />

the group has made the experience that the local management <strong>of</strong>ten is less conscious <strong>of</strong> its operations'<br />

institutional exposure, as well as the need to justify their 'licence to operate'.<br />

155<br />

Generally, strong local competition rather seems to increase competitors' efforts for building their<br />

reputations <strong>and</strong> their organisational legitimacy (cf. interview N°9: 7), in order to strengthen their<br />

competitive advantage.


Case Studies<br />

neighbouring regions, who invited the firm to set up business there: “It depends on<br />

your visibility <strong>and</strong> reputation. If both are good, as with Holcim, they might welcome<br />

you in different areas …. I was approached by many business entrepreneurs … asking<br />

me to come <strong>and</strong> have a look.” (cf. interview N°7: 11).<br />

In the short term, Holcim's various organisational units create value through their<br />

embedding capabilities on the following identified dimensions:<br />

- Operational efficiency. Depending on a country's history in labour conflicts, the<br />

embedding capabilities <strong>of</strong> Holcim's local plants improve their uptime, as there are<br />

fewer disruptions through labour tensions. In addition, the plants benefit from<br />

smoother day-to-day transactions with their stakeholders, thus further lowering<br />

their transaction costs.<br />

- Exploitation <strong>of</strong> positive externalities. Producing cement creates heat as a byproduct.<br />

In a h<strong>and</strong>ful <strong>of</strong> projects Holcim further utilises the produced heat, as for<br />

example in its Swiss cement plants <strong>of</strong> Eclépens, <strong>and</strong> Siggenthal, which together<br />

supply 600 households with district heating. Furthermore, five Chinese plants are<br />

about to invest in a power generation system, using low-temperature waste heat<br />

from the cement production process for steam-driven electricity generation. In<br />

India <strong>and</strong> Spain, Holcim experiments with the capture <strong>and</strong> storage <strong>of</strong> produced<br />

CO2, with which it intends to produce algae biomass, to be returned to the cement<br />

production process. Thus, it would partially close the energy loop <strong>and</strong> further<br />

reduce emissions from its activities. However, currently the economic importance<br />

<strong>of</strong> the exploitation <strong>of</strong> by-products remains negligible for Holcim.<br />

- Exploitation <strong>of</strong> other industry's externalities. In exactly the opposite direction,<br />

Holcim's use <strong>of</strong> co-processing <strong>and</strong> burning <strong>of</strong> industrial waste exploits by-products<br />

<strong>of</strong> other industries, thus helping to reduce production costs. Moreover, since these<br />

alternative fuels are seen as CO2 neutral, Holcim is making a further contribution<br />

towards sustainable development, achieving an improvement in its fuel mix, <strong>and</strong><br />

alleviating the growing waste disposal problem. Figure 5-14 illustrates the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> Holcim's use <strong>of</strong> alternative fuels over the past two decades.<br />

305


306<br />

% thermal energy from alternative fuels<br />

12<br />

10<br />

8<br />

6<br />

4<br />

2<br />

0<br />

3.7<br />

9.4<br />

11.0<br />

11.5<br />

11.6<br />

12.1<br />

Case Studies<br />

1990 … 2000 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009<br />

Figure 5-14: Holcim's development <strong>of</strong> alternative fuel use 156<br />

(2) Multi-site perspective. On its website 157 , Holcim states that it is<br />

more globally active than any other building materials group, but retains a strong<br />

foothold in each individual market. Geographic diversification stabilises earnings,<br />

as it helps to balance cyclical fluctuations in individual markets.<br />

This summary <strong>of</strong> Holcim's expansion logic from a holding perspective is being<br />

complemented from an operational perspective by the following excerpt <strong>of</strong> its mission<br />

statement (Holcim Ltd., 2004):<br />

We strive to leverage our shared experience <strong>and</strong> knowledge throughout our global<br />

network, actively applying this excellence to where it has the greatest benefit – in<br />

the markets <strong>and</strong> communities in which we operate.<br />

In the subsequent passages we will elaborate along the dimensions <strong>of</strong> our research<br />

framework, how Holcim creates value in its geographically diversified operations.<br />

(a) relations. Holcim's business model very actively encourages the exchange between<br />

its sites. <strong>The</strong> firm's country organisations are organised in regional clusters within<br />

which they frequently interact, complemented by regular country-level or regionallevel<br />

meetings, which serve as platforms for exchange. In addition, local <strong>and</strong> regional<br />

organisations are supported by service centres at the regional level, or by the central<br />

Holcim Group Support (HGRS), located at the firm's headquarters. Since all country<br />

organisations are well embedded, they mutually support each other in special projects,<br />

such as for example the preparation <strong>of</strong> market entry in neighbouring countries.<br />

156 Holcim, Annual Report 2009 (2010: 45).<br />

157<br />

'Geographic Diversification'. Retrieved March 28, 2010, from Holcim corporate website:<br />

www.holcim.com/index.php?id=4288&L=1.<br />

12.6


Case Studies<br />

Through such close coordination with regional peer organisations, local subsidiaries<br />

can more effectively gather market intelligence <strong>and</strong> are able to make use <strong>of</strong> the firm's<br />

network, in order to connect to the right people <strong>and</strong> institutions. Complementarily,<br />

they receive support from HGRS, which helps with procedural advice <strong>and</strong> the<br />

compilation <strong>of</strong> documents for any regulatory processes.<br />

Furthermore, Holcim fosters the development <strong>of</strong> corporate st<strong>and</strong>ards for its operations,<br />

which includes unified product st<strong>and</strong>ards. To this effect, it helps countries to close<br />

legislative gaps or to introduce best-practice st<strong>and</strong>ards for building materials - a<br />

process, which is also facilitated by the corporate centre. In another example from<br />

Holcim's operation in Azerbaijan, such a knowledge transfer was initiated by the firm's<br />

country manager in order to create new market opportunities. To this effect, the<br />

country organisation supported the local regulator in the adoption <strong>of</strong> EU st<strong>and</strong>ards for<br />

different cement products <strong>and</strong> for cement packaging. As a result, Holcim now is able<br />

to sell six cementitious products in the Azeri market instead <strong>of</strong> only two, <strong>and</strong> enjoys a<br />

significantly improved relationship with the regulator (cf. interview N°7: 13).<br />

(b) resources. Initially, the idea for the geographical diversification <strong>of</strong> Holcim was<br />

driven by considerations <strong>of</strong> financing <strong>and</strong> risk. Over time, however, other aspects <strong>of</strong><br />

resource sharing <strong>and</strong> synergy exploitation gained in importance, particularly in respect<br />

<strong>of</strong> the growing expertise <strong>and</strong> best practices in Holcim's operations. Today, the<br />

realisation <strong>of</strong> financial synergies is under the auspices <strong>of</strong> the group's financial holding,<br />

which coordinates <strong>and</strong> controls all financing activities. In contrast, for the realisation<br />

<strong>of</strong> industry-specific synergies the firm established the Holcim Group Support entity -<br />

as mentioned - which centrally accumulates Holcim's competencies through its people<br />

<strong>and</strong> by means <strong>of</strong> documentation. HGRS therefore has a turntable function with the<br />

purpose <strong>of</strong> disseminating industry-specific knowledge throughout the firm (cf.<br />

interview N°8: 1). Through this mix <strong>of</strong> central coordination, regional clustering, <strong>and</strong><br />

bottom-up local initiatives, Holcim has made synergy exploitation on all levels <strong>and</strong><br />

across geographies a central factor <strong>of</strong> its business model, as the subsequent examples<br />

illustrate.<br />

307


308<br />

Type <strong>of</strong><br />

synergy<br />

operative<br />

synergies<br />

Organisat.<br />

level<br />

regional<br />

level<br />

grouplevel<br />

(holding;<br />

HGRS)<br />

regional<br />

level;<br />

cross-site<br />

level<br />

grouplevel;<br />

BU<br />

level<br />

grouplevel;<br />

regional<br />

level;<br />

cross-sitelevel <br />

grouplevel;<br />

regional<br />

level<br />

(continued next page)<br />

Examples<br />

Case Studies<br />

Economies <strong>of</strong> scale in the firm's support activities through the regional<br />

clustering <strong>of</strong> country organisations: Examples for operative synergies are<br />

found in the fields <strong>of</strong> HR, market intelligence, purchasing, training &<br />

vocational education, market segmenting, product harmonisation,<br />

IT/s<strong>of</strong>tware applications, public affairs, political affairs <strong>and</strong> regulatory<br />

lobbying (interview N°7: 6). By turning each <strong>of</strong> the units in its regional<br />

clusters into a competence centre for one <strong>of</strong> these fields, knowledge is<br />

being exploited more efficiently (interview N°8: 4).<br />

Economies <strong>of</strong> scale in the group's financing-activities (holding), <strong>and</strong> in<br />

sharing <strong>of</strong> industry-related knowledge, e.g. in the fields <strong>of</strong> marketing,<br />

public affairs, <strong>and</strong> political affairs (HGRS).<br />

Avoidance <strong>of</strong> risk accumulation through inter-unit information exchange:<br />

By performing cross-informational checks between the organisational<br />

units, the firm is able to effectively detect <strong>and</strong> manage for example credit<br />

risks from accounts receivables, or other material risks to their ongoing<br />

operation (cf. interview N°7: 5).<br />

Economies <strong>of</strong> experience which facilitate the permitting process for new<br />

business development projects, or market entries in new countries: <strong>The</strong>se<br />

economies also apply to applications for EU funding, which <strong>of</strong>ten require<br />

preparation <strong>of</strong> detailed documents <strong>and</strong> information, too wide-ranging for<br />

smaller single-site firms.<br />

Exploitation <strong>of</strong> best practice exchange on all levels: Combination <strong>of</strong><br />

highly institutionalised exchanges with the multiplier effect <strong>of</strong> HGRS, <strong>and</strong><br />

spontaneous interaction on a need-basis. HGRS establishes platforms for<br />

knowledge exchange, providing opportunities to create links between the<br />

separate units.<br />

In 2009, Holcim implemented a newly developed knowledge management<br />

system (iShare) to capture <strong>and</strong> make accessible the key business<br />

knowledge <strong>of</strong> its companies <strong>and</strong> corporate staff units (Holcim Ltd., 2010).<br />

In addition, Holcim creates incentives for knowledge exchange, e.g.<br />

through internal competitions. In 2009, such a competition was organised<br />

to promote knowledge transfer in the field <strong>of</strong> near-to-market innovation.<br />

“Successful examples <strong>of</strong> innovative products, services <strong>and</strong> solutions were<br />

singled out <strong>and</strong> publicised group-wide. This created incentives for further<br />

market innovations <strong>and</strong> paved the way for successful multipliation <strong>and</strong><br />

advancement <strong>of</strong> the ideas at the local level” (Holcim Ltd., 2010: 31).<br />

Synergy exploitation in research <strong>and</strong> development at the corporate centre<br />

<strong>and</strong> on regional levels: Holcim's central R&D focuses on the identification<br />

<strong>of</strong> fundamental principles, complemented by decentralised market-based<br />

innovative activities in the subsidiaries. <strong>The</strong> active exchange between the<br />

centre <strong>and</strong> those local initiatives fosters the generation <strong>of</strong> new knowledge<br />

<strong>and</strong> innovation. As a result, group-wide roll-out <strong>of</strong> innovations is faster<br />

<strong>and</strong> more effective through sound internal cooperation.


Case Studies<br />

Type <strong>of</strong><br />

synergy<br />

market<br />

power<br />

synergies<br />

financial<br />

synergies<br />

corporate<br />

mgmt.<br />

synergies<br />

Organisat.<br />

level<br />

grouplevel<br />

regional<br />

level,<br />

cross-sitelevel <br />

grouplevel;<br />

regional<br />

level<br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel <br />

grouplevel<br />

(continued next page)<br />

Examples<br />

Minimum st<strong>and</strong>ards in the fields <strong>of</strong> work safety, operational safety (cf.<br />

interview N°8: 4), <strong>and</strong> regulatory compliance: Holcim has developed<br />

absolute minimum st<strong>and</strong>ards, which it enforces in all plants.<br />

Exploitation <strong>of</strong> efficiency synergies through joint use <strong>of</strong> assets: regional<br />

organisations, for example, (1) manage the storage <strong>of</strong> critical spare parts<br />

(expensive parts with long order lead-times) for their country clusters; (2)<br />

share semi-mobile concrete mixing equipment, which is needed in road<br />

construction; <strong>and</strong> (3) trans-nationally pool rail wagons, which allows a<br />

need-based dispatching <strong>of</strong> their rolling stock (cf. interview N°8: 5).<br />

Cost reductions through central corporate procurement, respectively a<br />

centrally-controlled st<strong>and</strong>ard procurement process: On different spatial<br />

scales (global, regional, local) the firm works together with its suppliers,<br />

in order to optimise resources <strong>and</strong> workflows. Three central procurement<br />

<strong>of</strong>fices in Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, Miami, <strong>and</strong> Singapore.<br />

Central purchasing includes the procurement <strong>of</strong> cement vehicles, critical<br />

plant components, <strong>and</strong> equipment.<br />

Exploitation <strong>of</strong> financial economies <strong>of</strong> scale through large internal<br />

financing possibilities, <strong>and</strong> the holding's efficient access to capital<br />

markets: Holcim combines central financing with additional selective decentral<br />

financing, where sensible (interview N°11: 1).<br />

Financial flexibility through a geographically diversified business<br />

portfolio: With a share <strong>of</strong> 52.4% (2009) <strong>of</strong> its net sales stemming from<br />

emerging markets, diversification means accelerated growth <strong>and</strong><br />

resistance against economic crises. With falling dem<strong>and</strong> expectations in<br />

Europe <strong>and</strong> the USA until 2012 (FT.com, 2009), Holcim can still expect<br />

smooth financial results through its growth markets.<br />

Reduced corporate risk due to improved liquidity planning, allowing the<br />

injection <strong>of</strong> money in temporarily distressed local operations (interview<br />

N°8: 8). Particularly during the banking crisis, such risk reduction proved<br />

valuable. It equally creates strategic options.<br />

Legally permissible reduction <strong>of</strong> the overall tax burden. Opportunities are<br />

limited, though, due to the location-fixity <strong>of</strong> Holcim's operation (interview<br />

N°8: 7).<br />

Capabilities in organisational design, <strong>and</strong> expertise in balancing local<br />

entrepreneurship <strong>and</strong> responsibility with the corporate centre's need for<br />

monitoring <strong>and</strong> control. In addition, Holcim has excellent performance<br />

appraisal systems which reward systemic thinking (cf. next line).<br />

Highly developed strategic capabilities, for optimal allocation <strong>of</strong> financial<br />

means regarding growth <strong>and</strong> expansion: <strong>The</strong> group fosters incremental<br />

growth through an intricate performance management system, which<br />

prescribes team- <strong>and</strong> group-based key performance indicators (KPI),<br />

309


310<br />

Type <strong>of</strong><br />

synergy<br />

Organisat.<br />

level<br />

grouplevel<br />

Examples<br />

instead <strong>of</strong> individual targets, thus enforcing communication <strong>and</strong><br />

interaction between its units (cf. interview N°7: 6).<br />

Case Studies<br />

Risk reduction <strong>and</strong> strategic decision support through Business Risk<br />

Management (BRM) department: BRM “aims systematically to recognise<br />

major risks – as well as opportunities – facing the company. Potential<br />

risks are identified <strong>and</strong> evaluated at an early stage. Countermeasures are<br />

then proposed <strong>and</strong> implemented at the appropriate level” (Holcim Ltd.,<br />

2010: 28). BRM takes into consideration all types <strong>of</strong> risk, including,<br />

including risks <strong>of</strong> non-compliance <strong>and</strong> reputation.<br />

Table 5-11: Overview on Holcim's synergy implementation<br />

Overall, Holcim very effectively exchanges its intangible resources through welldesigned<br />

organisational structures <strong>and</strong> processes, <strong>and</strong> by means <strong>of</strong> its central talent<br />

pool. Knowing that its success depends on people, it uses st<strong>and</strong>ardised processes to<br />

identify high-performers, experts <strong>and</strong> talents, <strong>and</strong> to prudently ensure succession<br />

planning. Thus, Holcim facilitates the best-possible dissemination <strong>of</strong> expertise<br />

throughout the company.<br />

(c) institutions. Holcim's relations with the various regulatory authorities are spatially<br />

divided. On a country-level, the country manager is responsible for underst<strong>and</strong>ing the<br />

regulations, processes, <strong>and</strong> potential issues, <strong>and</strong> for managing the relations with the<br />

national regulatory bodies. Although local managers receive support in the<br />

communication to <strong>of</strong>ficial bodies from HGRS' communication department, specific<br />

support is challenging due to country-specific conditions <strong>and</strong> regulatory frameworks.<br />

Particularly in Asian countries, communication to <strong>of</strong>ficial bodies is assisted by local<br />

minority partners, who help overcoming any liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness (cf. interview<br />

N°8: 14).<br />

<strong>The</strong> corporate centre significantly creates value by means <strong>of</strong> well structured<br />

management systems <strong>and</strong> effective corporate governance, which are a precondition for<br />

the group’s credibility <strong>and</strong> good reputation. Holcim's subsidiaries “are given clear<br />

guidelines in all key areas <strong>of</strong> the business, from technology <strong>and</strong> environmentally<br />

friendly production to human resources <strong>and</strong> finance” (Holcim Ltd., 2010: 27) <strong>and</strong> a<br />

“broad Code <strong>of</strong> Conduct ensures that all employees know what rights <strong>and</strong> obligations<br />

apply in the work environment” (ibid.: 25). As a means to ensure proper adherence to<br />

the group's st<strong>and</strong>ards, Holcim has installed an independent body responsible for<br />

internal audits, which is not confined to financial audits but also monitors compliance


Case Studies<br />

with external <strong>and</strong> internal guidelines. Particular attention goes to the functioning <strong>of</strong><br />

internal management <strong>and</strong> control systems, including the examination <strong>of</strong> the reliability<br />

<strong>and</strong> completeness <strong>of</strong> financial <strong>and</strong> operational information; <strong>of</strong> the systems for<br />

controlling compliance with internal <strong>and</strong> external directives; <strong>and</strong> whether business<br />

assets are secure (Holcim Ltd., 2010: 28). Through these elaborate internal checks <strong>and</strong><br />

balances, Holcim strengthens confidence among investors, business partners,<br />

employees, <strong>and</strong> the public at large.<br />

In the fields <strong>of</strong> political <strong>and</strong> regulatory affairs, Holcim's regional <strong>and</strong> country<br />

organisations exercise support functions to help the individual sites in their<br />

management <strong>of</strong> regulatory issues. Such support is particularly valuable in case <strong>of</strong><br />

complex procedures <strong>and</strong> investigations. Holcim Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, for example, centrally<br />

coordinates soil investigations, which are necessary to identify potential<br />

contaminations from past firm activities, or negotiates voluntary emission reduction<br />

plans for its plants with the respective local authorities.<br />

5.3.8 Summary<br />

Holcim's location-fixity originates from its upstream resource dependence <strong>and</strong> from<br />

downstream dependence on market proximity. As a fully private company it<br />

experiences no location-fixity from its ownership structure. Through its global<br />

presence Holcim recognised the consequences <strong>of</strong> liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness early on,<br />

hence attributing importance to subsidiaries' local embedding, the respect <strong>of</strong> local<br />

culture <strong>and</strong> the local way <strong>of</strong> doing business. Its subsidiaries therefore intensively<br />

engage in local stakeholder dialogues <strong>and</strong> CSR activities, taking responsibility <strong>of</strong> their<br />

impact on the local environment <strong>and</strong> the local population's livelihood, which Holcim<br />

aspires to improve in a sustainable way. From a multi-site perspective Holcim has<br />

identified fields, where it requires all entities to comply with corporate best practice<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ards in order to capture synergies. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, political <strong>and</strong> regulatory<br />

issues are clearly h<strong>and</strong>led on a regional or national basis, where the knowledge <strong>of</strong> the<br />

local institutional environment is highest. Importantly, Holcim encourages<br />

decentralised inter-unit exchange to leverage its know-how <strong>and</strong> to foster innovation. In<br />

addition to these bottom-up need-based interactions, the corporate centre facilitates<br />

such exchange in a structured way. Thus, Holcim is able to leverage economies <strong>of</strong><br />

experience across its operations, to capture synergies from its financial power <strong>and</strong> its<br />

global risk management, <strong>and</strong> to exploit the local strengths <strong>of</strong> its location-dependent<br />

units in day-to-day operation.<br />

311


312<br />

5.4 Cross case comparison<br />

Case Studies<br />

<strong>The</strong> central notion <strong>of</strong> theory-building case research is to use the associated insights to<br />

inductively develop theory over time. In this process “theory is emergent in the sense<br />

that it is situated in <strong>and</strong> developed by recognising patterns <strong>of</strong> relationships among<br />

constructs within <strong>and</strong> across cases <strong>and</strong> their underlying logical arguments” (Eisenhardt<br />

& Graebner, 2007: 25). Our choice <strong>of</strong> multiple cases therefore allows to follow<br />

replication logic (Eisenhardt, 1989), considering them as discrete experiments which<br />

enable “comparisons that clarify whether an emergent finding is simply idiosyncratic<br />

to a single case or consistently replicated by several cases” (Eisenhardt & Graebner,<br />

2007: 27). With the objective to increase the robustness <strong>of</strong> our findings, we therefore<br />

will subsequently compare our hitherto individually described cases, with an interest in<br />

identifying commonalities but also relevant differences.<br />

5.4.1 Comparison <strong>of</strong> location-fixity<br />

<strong>The</strong> core construct <strong>of</strong> our research framework, location-fixity, applies to all three case<br />

study objects, albeit with differences in intensity on the suggested dimensions (cf.<br />

Table 5-12). All three firms share a dependence on natural resources (e.g. water, l<strong>and</strong>,<br />

limestone) <strong>and</strong> on tangible assets (power plants, airport infrastructure, quarry &<br />

cement plants), but differ in their dependence on market-proximity. As it is essential<br />

for an airport to be near to its catchment area, customer proximity is less vital for<br />

cement manufacturers, where product reach is directly correlating with transportation<br />

costs <strong>and</strong> regional competition. <strong>The</strong> least significance <strong>of</strong> market proximity is<br />

observable for power providers, whose product is - in theory - transportable in<br />

economically viable ways. However, in reality restrictions to transportation over long<br />

distance exist through the limited capacity <strong>of</strong> the transmission networks <strong>and</strong> due to<br />

network usage fees. On the dimension <strong>of</strong> ownership, Axpo <strong>and</strong> Zurich Airport are<br />

state-owned enterprises - Axpo in full public ownership <strong>and</strong> Zurich Airport being<br />

38.3% publicly owned - while Holcim is a fully private company. <strong>The</strong> ownership<br />

dimension therefore represents the most interesting variation in location-fixity between<br />

the three case study objects.<br />

How does the public ownership affect Zurich Airport <strong>and</strong> Axpo, which both are in an<br />

ongoing process <strong>of</strong> international expansion? Interestingly, for both firms there were no<br />

indications for any obvious conflicts <strong>of</strong> interest in the past decade. However, as both


Case Studies<br />

firms have a sovereign mission 158 which they need to fulfil, the awareness is high, that<br />

their economic success represents the key to their entrepreneurial freedom. Until<br />

recently, Axpo therefore explicitly stated in its mission: “We want to be constantly<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>itable <strong>and</strong> create added value for our shareholders. In this way we have the<br />

freedom to act <strong>and</strong> that we will remain competitive” 159 . This focus on value creation as<br />

a means <strong>of</strong> retaining entrepreneurial freedom has strong parallels with FZ, which<br />

equally perceives its pr<strong>of</strong>itable operation, as well as its high quality st<strong>and</strong>ards in<br />

Zurich as a facilitating factor to its international engagement. However, Axpo's<br />

expansion path so far remained focused on Europe, <strong>and</strong> - with few exceptions -<br />

concentrated on energy trading, involving less up-front capital investments <strong>and</strong> being<br />

an essentially mobile (knowledge-driven) business. FZ, on the other h<strong>and</strong>, seeks to<br />

exp<strong>and</strong> in geographically more distant countries. Clearly driven by risk-considerations,<br />

FZ restricts its engagements to minority shareholdings, combined with management<br />

contracts for which no major sunk costs are incurred. It is unclear, however, to what<br />

extent its obligations towards the public stakeholders influenced its propensity for risk<br />

in recent years, potentially bounding its aggressiveness in bidding processes for<br />

international airport projects.<br />

In contrast, Holcim's biggest shareholder is a member <strong>of</strong> the founding family, with the<br />

rest <strong>of</strong> the share capital freely floated. Although Holcim very prudently fosters its<br />

international expansion, it has no limitations from potential target system conflicts<br />

with its owners, thus being able to decide on risks <strong>and</strong> areas <strong>of</strong> geographical<br />

engagement from a purely firm-centred value-driven perspective.<br />

158<br />

In the case <strong>of</strong> Axpo, the sovereign mission anchored in its vision, combined with the intent to go<br />

international, read as follows: "We aspire to dependability: As a Swiss energy group, we st<strong>and</strong> for<br />

security, quality <strong>and</strong> sustainability. We are therefore locally anchored <strong>and</strong> globally present [italics<br />

added]." (retrieved September 14, 2010, from Axpo corporate website:<br />

www.axpo.ch/axpo/en/home_multi/konzern/auf_einen_blick/vision.html). Similarly Zurich Airport's<br />

mission reads: "We connect Switzerl<strong>and</strong> to the rest <strong>of</strong> the world, we welcome our guests all around the<br />

clock, we develop projects in Switzerl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> abroad, <strong>and</strong> we distinguish ourselves through<br />

'Swissness' [italics added]"(retrieved September 14, from Zurich Airport corporate website:<br />

www.zurich-airport.com/desktopdefault.aspx/tabid-546/).<br />

159<br />

'We have a mission'. Retrieved July 14, 2010 from Axpo corporate website:<br />

www.axpo.ch/axpo/en/neue_energien_multi/konzern/auf_einen_blick/leitbild.html.<br />

313


314<br />

Characteristic Axpo Zurich<br />

Airport<br />

Upstream<br />

Natural Resource & Tangible Asset Dependence<br />

Downstream<br />

Dependence on Market Proximity<br />

Ownership<br />

Dependence on Owners' Utility Function<br />

� fully applicable / ~ weakly applicable / � not applicable<br />

� � �<br />

~ � �<br />

� � �<br />

Table 5-12: Cross-case comparison <strong>of</strong> location-fixity: Axpo, Zurich Airport <strong>and</strong> Holcim<br />

Case Studies<br />

Holcim<br />

5.4.2 Commonalities <strong>and</strong> differences in institutional exposure<br />

On the dimension <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure all three firms are concerned with civilian<br />

interest groups <strong>and</strong> their public stakeholders, as both have decisive influence on the<br />

feasibility <strong>of</strong> new projects, as well as on the pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong> existing ones. Due to the<br />

externalities <strong>of</strong> their industries, all three case study objects have to regard the<br />

expectations from environmental groups <strong>and</strong> interest groups, which also represent the<br />

local community. While Axpo discusses its projects with nature conservationists,<br />

fishing <strong>and</strong> neighbourhood associations, FZ is more concerned with various noisecentred<br />

associations, <strong>and</strong> Holcim maintains a close dialogue with the local community<br />

<strong>and</strong> their various forms <strong>of</strong> organisation, based on the high impact <strong>of</strong> their operation<br />

<strong>and</strong> the resulting responsibility for the local livelihoods. In respect <strong>of</strong> their employee<br />

relations, Axpo <strong>and</strong> FZ have no history <strong>of</strong> labour issues across their operations. In<br />

contrast, Holcim occasionally experiences labour conflicts, which partly are related to<br />

its industry, respectively to the traditions <strong>of</strong> its host countries.<br />

With view at the public stakeholders, Axpo is closely interacting with local<br />

administrations <strong>and</strong> the regulator, being aware <strong>of</strong> their essential role for new projects<br />

<strong>and</strong> other undertakings in business development. Most importantly, Axpo needs to<br />

limit the attempts <strong>of</strong> local public stakeholders at rent appropriation, particularly in preproject<br />

negotiation phases. Furthermore, Axpo is familiar with the effects <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

chauvinism 160 , which it has come across in trying to extend its presence to new<br />

regions, where other local champions are rooted. FZ's exposure to public stakeholders<br />

160 I.e. the regional form <strong>of</strong> economic chauvinism, as Axpo experiences similar effects across different<br />

regions in Switzerl<strong>and</strong>.


Case Studies<br />

also pertains to local administrations, <strong>and</strong> particularly to the regulator. In its<br />

international projects it occasionally experiences the difficulty to get credible<br />

commitments from governments. Particularly in phases with forthcoming elections, it<br />

is prone to becoming a target <strong>of</strong> political opportunism, such as the politically<br />

motivated renegotiation <strong>of</strong> airport tariffs or the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> higher investments in<br />

airport infrastructure. Furthermore, presently the regulation for airport charges is being<br />

reworked in a number <strong>of</strong> states, putting the airport operator at risk <strong>of</strong> a more<br />

disadvantageous <strong>and</strong> investor-unfriendly regulatory practice 161 . With view at its Zurich<br />

operation, the political atmosphere related to the airport's activities is very emotional,<br />

representing one <strong>of</strong> the critical topics for local politicians <strong>and</strong> the local administration.<br />

In this environment the conflicting public policy objectives become apparent, with<br />

which the airport struggles in its daily operation. At last, Holcim's biggest concern<br />

regarding its public stakeholders pertains to regulation. While it actively tries to shape<br />

regulation for new solutions in respect to its production processes <strong>and</strong> technologies 162 ,<br />

increasingly strict prescriptions may represent a regulatory risk for continued<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>itable local operation. Furthermore, the increasing automation <strong>of</strong> plant operations<br />

<strong>and</strong> the firm's consequent policy with regard to dem<strong>and</strong>-driven production, leading to<br />

occasional shut-downs <strong>of</strong> plants in economic downturns, exposes the firm to local<br />

pressure pertaining to the preservation <strong>of</strong> jobs.<br />

Importantly, the reach <strong>of</strong> the firm's externalities may serve as an indicator <strong>of</strong> the<br />

resulting complexity to find adequate solutions for stakeholders: Holcim, on one h<strong>and</strong>,<br />

is able to resolve any effects from its externalities on a purely local level, as possible<br />

noise <strong>and</strong> atmospheric emissions affect a defined range surrounding the plant. On the<br />

other extreme, Zurich Airport's activities affect a large area, partly depending on the<br />

approved l<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>and</strong> departure regime. Any change in such a regime favours certain<br />

residents in the region, but necessarily puts other parts <strong>of</strong> the population at<br />

disadvantage. As a result, FZ - at least with regard to its Zurich operation - is currently<br />

caught in a literal straightjacket, unable to make alterations to its current operational<br />

mode 163 . Axpo may be seen as somewhere in between: its hydro power plants affect<br />

161<br />

Such as for example price-cap regulation on a single-till basis, where commercial revenues cover a<br />

portion <strong>of</strong> the airport’s overall fixed costs.<br />

162<br />

E.g. for the use <strong>of</strong> alternative materials for its kiln fuelling.<br />

163<br />

This view is underlined by a statement from a Zurich Airport executive with regard to the<br />

significance <strong>of</strong> externalities for the local population: "Da liegt natürlich auch der wesentliche<br />

Unterschied zu Holcim. Wenn Holcim im Untersiggenthal den Beton aus dem Silo in den Lastwagen<br />

verlädt, dann staubt das. Für dieses Problem kann Holcim zusammen mit der lokalen Bevölkerung vor<br />

315


316<br />

Case Studies<br />

the local ecosystem, depending on the scope <strong>of</strong> the project-externalities which most<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten can be discussed with a small range <strong>of</strong> stakeholders. An altogether different<br />

perspective needs to be taken for its nuclear plant, which not only affects the local<br />

population, but theoretically puts large surrounding areas at risk. Any special<br />

occurrences, planned changes, extensions or even new projects therefore need to be<br />

considered from a large-scale view on stakeholders, far beyond the regulatory<br />

perspective.<br />

While the individual issues <strong>of</strong> the three firms with their stakeholder groups are<br />

different <strong>and</strong> partly industry-related, the consequences <strong>and</strong> resulting need for<br />

stakeholder collaboration <strong>and</strong> local embedding are similar <strong>and</strong> will be discussed in the<br />

subsequent section. Table 5-13 provides an overview on the institutional exposure <strong>of</strong><br />

the three case objects towards the individual stakeholder groups.<br />

Institutional exposure from stakeholder group Axpo Zurich<br />

Airport<br />

<strong>Local</strong> community � � �<br />

Civilian interest groups � � �<br />

Customers ~ ~ �<br />

Suppliers ~ � ~<br />

Service partners � � ~<br />

Employees � � ~<br />

Public shareholder � � �<br />

Government: political dimension � � �<br />

Regulator: law & order dimension � � �<br />

� high / ~ medium / � low or none<br />

Table 5-13: Cross-case comparison <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure: Axpo, Zurich Airport <strong>and</strong> Holcim<br />

Holcim<br />

5.4.3 Comparison <strong>of</strong> legitimisation <strong>and</strong> embedding strategies<br />

<strong>The</strong> activities <strong>of</strong> our case objects with regard to organisational legitimisation <strong>and</strong><br />

embedding are not unique to these industries, nor are they truly innovative - most<br />

firms in one way or the other make use <strong>of</strong> similar means to gain the acceptance <strong>of</strong> their<br />

local environment. However, the intensity with which the three companies pursue<br />

them may be pointing towards the high significance <strong>and</strong> value impact that legitimacy<br />

has for them as characteristic UCFs.<br />

Ort eine lokale Lösung finden. Das kann der Flughafen Zürich nicht, denn das System ist ein komplett<br />

<strong>and</strong>eres und es herrscht auch ein <strong>and</strong>erer politischer Aufheizungsgrad vor…" (Interview N° 23: 9).


Case Studies<br />

With a look at Axpo, its organisational legitimacy currently gains a particular<br />

significance in view <strong>of</strong> two facts: (1) Axpo's nuclear plant in Beznau will reach the end<br />

<strong>of</strong> its life cycle shortly past 2020, <strong>and</strong> the company has already requested regulatory<br />

outline approval 164 for a technologically more advanced replacement plant in 2008.<br />

Apart from the regulatory green light, the public opinion on nuclear power will<br />

ultimately be decisive for project implementation. In addition, public opinion on the<br />

project will be influenced by the general trust in Axpo as a responsible plant owner<br />

<strong>and</strong> operator. (2) Many <strong>of</strong> the firm's hydropower concessions will expire in the<br />

upcoming years, which will expose the firm to negotiations for higher rent<br />

appropriation, respectively which will require various costly admissions to its local<br />

stakeholders. Not surprisingly, the firm therefore intensively engages in lobbying <strong>and</strong><br />

image-building, on top <strong>of</strong> the regular embedding activities. From a general embedding<br />

perspective, particularly Axpo's capabilities to identify <strong>and</strong> involve all relevant<br />

stakeholders from the earliest project stages should be highlighted. In addition, its<br />

ability to sense underlying issues, motivations, <strong>and</strong> expectations <strong>of</strong> stakeholders, not<br />

obvious from the outset, <strong>and</strong> to consequently find optimised solutions to satisfy the<br />

real concerns <strong>of</strong> stakeholders certainly are mentionable key success factors. As a<br />

consequence, these capabilities allow Axpo to make concessions exactly where they<br />

matter.<br />

From a different angle, also FZ finds itself in a phase, where intensive embedding<br />

activities are required. As Zurich airport is approaching its capacity limit 165 , already<br />

having to turn down dem<strong>and</strong> in its daily peak periods, FZ requires high trust <strong>and</strong><br />

legitimacy from its stakeholders to initiate the needed infrastructure expansions. <strong>The</strong><br />

long time to implementation <strong>of</strong> such schemes, due to planning requirements, as well as<br />

legal <strong>and</strong> regulatory approval periods, positively impact the airport's efforts to embed<br />

itself <strong>and</strong> to build goodwill with its affected stakeholders. Furthermore, since its<br />

privatisation in 2000, FZ has been regularly engaging in large-scale projects in Zurich,<br />

which in one way or the other affected airport operation 166 . <strong>The</strong>se projects include its<br />

fifth expansion phase, major system adjustments due to Switzerl<strong>and</strong>'s admission to the<br />

Schengen Agreement, the renovation <strong>and</strong> operational re-integration <strong>of</strong> its Dock B 167 ,<br />

164 I.e. Rahmenbewilligungsgesuch.<br />

165 From a peak-hour perspective.<br />

166<br />

Mostly with regard to passenger processes, but to some extent also affecting aircraft processes.<br />

167<br />

Dock B was closed as a passenger terminal for almost a decade after the opening <strong>of</strong> Dock E in<br />

2003. <strong>The</strong> decision was taken due to a sharp decrease in passenger traffic in the wake <strong>of</strong> the terrorist<br />

317


318<br />

Case Studies<br />

as well as the planned introduction <strong>of</strong> a central security process in 2011. In a longerterm<br />

outlook, FZ will also significantly develop its l<strong>and</strong>side area with the construction<br />

<strong>of</strong> a large multi-purpose structure called '<strong>The</strong> Circle', with expected construction costs<br />

<strong>of</strong> CHF 1 billion 168 . All these projects require FZ to be on good terms with its<br />

surrounding communities, the local population, <strong>and</strong> the regulatory authorities which<br />

need to approve the projects <strong>and</strong> their related environmental effects. FZ therefore very<br />

consciously maintains good relationships with administrative <strong>and</strong> political<br />

representatives from its neighbourhood. In this endeavour, it prioritises its efforts<br />

according to its stakeholders' degree <strong>of</strong> affectedness. With regard to its international<br />

projects, FZ benefits from its experiences with a politically challenging environment in<br />

Zurich, thus being able to empathically involve relevant stakeholders in airport issues,<br />

<strong>and</strong> to culturally sensitively respond to stakeholder expectations.<br />

Figure 5-15 illustrates the increased focus <strong>of</strong> Axpo <strong>and</strong> FZ (at Zurich airport) on<br />

organisational embedding from a concession life cycle perspective. Both firms are in<br />

need <strong>of</strong> high legitimacy <strong>and</strong> trust, in order to successfully master major infrastructure<br />

projects in the mid-term. Consequently, both firms should display intensified<br />

embedding activities over the next years.<br />

intensity <strong>of</strong> embedding activities<br />

evaluation<br />

<strong>of</strong> location<br />

firm site<br />

approval<br />

bidding &<br />

negotiation<br />

construction &<br />

start-up preparation<br />

government<br />

concession<br />

approval<br />

start <strong>of</strong><br />

operation<br />

embedding focus<br />

<strong>of</strong> Zurich Airport<br />

negotiation<br />

for extension<br />

adjustment<br />

to operational<br />

scale or scope<br />

negotiation<br />

for concession<br />

renewal<br />

� � � � �<br />

Figure 5-15: Different embedding focus over asset lifetime - Axpo <strong>and</strong> Zurich Airport<br />

embedding focus<br />

<strong>of</strong> Axpo<br />

t<br />

end <strong>of</strong><br />

concession<br />

attacks <strong>of</strong> September 11, 2001, <strong>and</strong> the ensuing grounding <strong>of</strong> the home carrier Swissair in October<br />

2001.<br />

168<br />

<strong>The</strong> financing structure <strong>of</strong> the project has not been finalised at the time <strong>of</strong> concluding this<br />

dissertation. FZ intends to implement the scheme together with third party investors.


Case Studies<br />

Holcim, as a truly global firm, is continuously engaged in all stages <strong>of</strong> the embedding<br />

process, due to its large international portfolio <strong>and</strong> the different life cycles <strong>of</strong> these<br />

operations. Of all three case objects, Holcim also seems to have the most structured<br />

approach to local embedding <strong>and</strong> to CSR activities, centrally providing guidelines to<br />

its subsidiaries with regard to stakeholder materiality reviews, stakeholder dialogues,<br />

<strong>and</strong> CSR activities in general. By proactively contributing to high regulatory st<strong>and</strong>ards<br />

also in less developed countries, <strong>and</strong> through its objective to promote international<br />

unification <strong>of</strong> its industry's regulation, the firm demonstrates high ethical st<strong>and</strong>ards,<br />

thus creating goodwill in its local operations. <strong>The</strong> same applies to its unified emission<br />

monitoring <strong>and</strong> reporting, <strong>and</strong> its valuable strategic cooperations with reputed<br />

organisations, such as GTZ, in order to develop more energy efficient production<br />

methods <strong>and</strong> to lower its externalities.<br />

In respect <strong>of</strong> Axpo's legitimisation strategy, the firm is able to rely on a mutual lock-in<br />

with a part <strong>of</strong> its public stakeholders, as the most politically dem<strong>and</strong>ing parties are also<br />

its shareholders. In its geographical core regions, Axpo therefore benefits from the<br />

positive interests that the public stakeholders take in its ability to pursue its public<br />

mission. All the same, this mutual lock-in becomes a liability in regions, where it has<br />

no historical ties, since the respective public administrations have an interest in their<br />

own local energy champions. In respect <strong>of</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong>'s energy policy, Axpo has a<br />

quasi-lock in with the national political decision-makers due to factual constraints:<br />

with current energy consumption levels <strong>and</strong> environmental protection st<strong>and</strong>ards, there<br />

is no known 'green' alternative to nuclear power - apart from importing <strong>of</strong>ten less<br />

'green' power from neighbouring countries. In comparison, FZ in its Zurich operation<br />

equally has a mutual lock-in with its public stake- <strong>and</strong> shareholders. This lock-in,<br />

however, is bounded by the Canton <strong>of</strong> Zurich's ownership strategy, wherein the canton<br />

clearly prioritises the protection <strong>of</strong> the population <strong>of</strong> negative externalities,<br />

respectively balances these protective considerations with the airport's cantonal <strong>and</strong><br />

national mission to provide adequate infrastructure 169 . Thus, Zurich airport's ongoing<br />

operation (<strong>and</strong> thus the going concern <strong>of</strong> its operator) is ensured through this set-up, as<br />

169 See also Article 1 <strong>of</strong> the cantonal Airport Law ("Flughafengesetz," 1999): "Der Staat fördert den<br />

Flughafen Zürich zur Sicherstellung seiner volks- und verkehrswirtschaftlichen Interessen. Er<br />

berücksichtigt dabei den Schutz der Bevölkerung vor schädlichen oder lästigen Auswirkungen des<br />

Flughafenbetriebs."; respectively Article 36a <strong>of</strong> the national Aviation Law ("Luftfahrtgesetz," 1948):<br />

"Der Konzessionär ist verpflichtet, den Flughafen unter Vorbehalt der im Betriebsreglement<br />

festgelegten Einschränkungen für alle Luftfahrzeuge im nationalen und internationalen Verkehr zur<br />

Verfügung zu stellen, einen ordnungsgemässen, sicheren Betrieb zu gewährleisten und für die dafür<br />

erforderliche Infrastruktur zu sorgen."<br />

319


320<br />

Case Studies<br />

has also been seen during FZ's crisis after the grounding <strong>of</strong> its home-carrier Swissair in<br />

2001. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the development <strong>of</strong> further capacity currently is <strong>and</strong> will<br />

remain restricted in the foreseeable future, due to political circumstances to which also<br />

the Canton <strong>of</strong> Zurich is subjected. Holcim, as a fully private company does not have<br />

strong factual lock-ins in its operations. It therefore needs to create them in the<br />

negotiation phases <strong>of</strong> its international engagements, thus reducing its project risks,<br />

securing pr<strong>of</strong>itable operation on a sustained basis, <strong>and</strong> having clear exit options in case<br />

<strong>of</strong> deterioration <strong>of</strong> the conditions in its institutional environment. In the example <strong>of</strong> the<br />

recent expropriation <strong>and</strong> nationalisation <strong>of</strong> its operation in Venezuela, for example,<br />

Holcim was able to limit its exposure due to an investment protection agreement<br />

between Switzerl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Venezuela - a safeguard between states that is intended to<br />

deter unilateral state-actions <strong>of</strong> this type. Although the firm had to cede control <strong>of</strong> its<br />

plant <strong>and</strong> was forced to leave in 2008, it received a decent compensation, according to<br />

industry experts, in September 2010 (NZZ Online, 13 September 2010).<br />

Finally, all three case objects have capabilities to adequately adapt locally. While for<br />

Axpo, local adaptation mostly means to adapt to the specific local political<br />

circumstances in different regions <strong>of</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, where it chooses to facilitate<br />

interactions through local gatekeepers, FZ <strong>and</strong> Holcim also interact with differing<br />

institutional environments on a global scale. <strong>The</strong> two last-mentioned both explicitly<br />

stress the importance <strong>of</strong> taking the local firm- <strong>and</strong> institutional cultures as reference<br />

points, both having the capability to identify relevant local characteristics <strong>and</strong><br />

strengths, which they take as a basis to work with the local culture. In the case <strong>of</strong> FZ,<br />

local adaptation additionally has an architectural <strong>and</strong> design aspect, whereby the<br />

locally managed airports need to be given a distinct local look <strong>and</strong> feel, with the aim to<br />

make them symbols <strong>of</strong> regional pride.<br />

5.4.4 Comparison <strong>of</strong> value creation effects<br />

Single site perspective. With a look at the management <strong>of</strong> individual sites, all three<br />

case objects have a conscious approach to local embedding, instrumentally building<br />

their image in order stimulate a constructive local business environment. Differences,<br />

however, exist with regard to the breadth <strong>of</strong> these embedding strategies, as well as to<br />

the degree <strong>of</strong> structure with which the embedding <strong>and</strong> legitimisation process is<br />

furthered. Holcim, with its 'triple bottom-line' philosophy - embracing the economic,<br />

social <strong>and</strong> environmental dimension <strong>of</strong> value creation - has developed the most farreaching<br />

approach towards stakeholder involvement <strong>and</strong> corporate social<br />

responsibility. Through its holistic approach it pursues economic pr<strong>of</strong>it, while giving


Case Studies<br />

clear guidance to its employees on the company values <strong>and</strong> ethical st<strong>and</strong>ards with<br />

which pr<strong>of</strong>it-generation needs to be in accord. Consequently, in exemplary cases the<br />

firm is even able to combine CSR-minded projects with pr<strong>of</strong>it-generation, as<br />

illustrated in its 'Mi Casa' initiative (see also chapter 4.8.4). Clearly, Holcim has<br />

recognised the value <strong>of</strong> high organisational legitimacy with regard to value creation<br />

opportunities <strong>and</strong> the creation <strong>of</strong> options. As has been shown, its embedding<br />

capabilities positively affect transaction costs, the exploitation <strong>of</strong> positive externalities,<br />

<strong>and</strong> operational efficiency.<br />

In comparison, FZ- due to its rather loose links with its international airports <strong>and</strong> its<br />

minority shareholdings - has no unified approach to organisational embedding. In its<br />

Zurich operation, the firm has an intricate approach to stakeholder involvement, not<br />

least due to the complex <strong>and</strong> politically sensitive environment. It systematically<br />

involves stakeholders - particularly the political <strong>and</strong> public ones - <strong>and</strong> returns some <strong>of</strong><br />

its created value to the externality-affected parts <strong>of</strong> the local population in the form <strong>of</strong><br />

noise abatement measures 170 , to which it is legally obliged. <strong>The</strong> resulting<br />

organisational legitimacy allows it to create <strong>and</strong> ultimately realise options for further<br />

revenue generation, as the aforementioned examples <strong>of</strong> the smoking lounges <strong>and</strong><br />

arrival duty free illustrate. However, its value creation possibilities are <strong>and</strong> will remain<br />

bounded by the limitations to develop or even adapt its aviation infrastructure. In its<br />

international operations, FZ experiences less restrictive environments in respect <strong>of</strong><br />

growth opportunities, but <strong>of</strong>ten is prone to more uncertainty with regard to institutional<br />

<strong>and</strong> political stability. Depending on the political situation <strong>of</strong> its host country, which<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten is influenced by election cycles, continuous reputation building with the local<br />

population, politicians, <strong>and</strong> public administrations is crucially contributing to value<br />

creation, respectively serves as an 'insurance' against value destruction. Importantly,<br />

FZ's embedding capabilities in Zurich <strong>and</strong> in its other operations are effectively<br />

lowering transaction costs (<strong>and</strong> liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness), have a positive impact on its<br />

operational efficiency, <strong>and</strong> support it in the exploitation <strong>of</strong> positive externalities.<br />

At last, Axpo's approach may be placed in between Holcim's unified <strong>and</strong> very<br />

systematic, <strong>and</strong> Zurich Airport's de-central embedding activities. In line with its selfconception<br />

as a financial holding, it leaves the local embedding strategies completely<br />

to the de-central units, while pursuing national lobbying issues on the holding-level. In<br />

170<br />

<strong>The</strong>se measures are financed through a fraction <strong>of</strong> the airport's passenger fee which is dedicated to<br />

noise abatement, <strong>and</strong> which is administered within the airport's noise protection funds<br />

('Lärmschutzfonds').<br />

321


322<br />

Case Studies<br />

project acquisitions or concession renewals, however, the corporate centre -<br />

respectively the responsible division - is very diligent to involve the relevant<br />

stakeholders early on, <strong>and</strong> to create respective value propositions, thus significantly<br />

increasing the probability <strong>of</strong> obtaining the necessary approvals for implementation <strong>and</strong><br />

positively influencing the project's overall conditions. Thus, although such proactive<br />

stakeholder involvement incurs costs in the form <strong>of</strong> 'appeasement', Axpo creates value<br />

by ultimately reaching closure <strong>of</strong> project deals, which might otherwise be delayed or<br />

fail altogether. Similar to FZ's situation, Axpo also needs to pay attention to the<br />

expectations <strong>and</strong> needs <strong>of</strong> local stakeholders on an ongoing basis. <strong>The</strong>reby it may<br />

avoid expensive legal battles <strong>and</strong> hardening <strong>of</strong> attitudes <strong>of</strong> neglected parties, <strong>and</strong><br />

preserve valuable options for the firm's future development. By means <strong>of</strong> its<br />

embedding capabilities, Axpo therefore is able to save on transaction costs, to gain in<br />

operational efficiency - effectively illustrated by the example <strong>of</strong> the consecutive<br />

hydropower plants in the Maggia valley - to lower its financing costs, <strong>and</strong> to valorise<br />

positive externalities.<br />

Multi-site perspective. Also with regard to value creation among multiple locationfixed<br />

sites, our case objects differ quite significantly in their structuring <strong>of</strong> inter-unit<br />

exchanges, respectively in their interaction between the corporate parent <strong>and</strong> the<br />

individual units. Again, Holcim employs the most structured approach, having firmly<br />

anchored the exchange <strong>and</strong> diffusion <strong>of</strong> best practices throughout the firm in its<br />

strategy. An important pillar in this strategy implementation is the corporate HGRS<br />

unit, which specifically supports knowledge transfer, fosters innovation <strong>and</strong> facilitates<br />

the interaction between its units <strong>and</strong> geographies. <strong>The</strong>se activities are complemented<br />

by its global iShare system, which serves as a knowledge exchange platform, <strong>and</strong> by<br />

the firm's performance management system, whose key performance indicators<br />

encourage inter-unit interaction. Furthermore, Holcim has st<strong>and</strong>ardised key corporate<br />

processes, thus exploiting its value creation potential in its production. In addition, it<br />

allows the local management to concentrate resources on locally specific issues, <strong>and</strong> to<br />

nurture relations with various stakeholder groups (Holcim Ltd, 2010a). Holcim, as a<br />

location-dependent multi-site firm, therefore creates value through the realisation <strong>of</strong><br />

operative synergies such as the organisational clustering <strong>of</strong> support functions, central<br />

procurement opportunities, <strong>and</strong> the management <strong>of</strong> critical spare parts. With regard to<br />

financial <strong>and</strong> corporate synergies, Holcim is able to optimise its financing costs, to<br />

better diversify its risks, <strong>and</strong> to pr<strong>of</strong>essionally manage its overall risks.<br />

Similar ways <strong>of</strong> value creation are pursued by Axpo. As is the case for Holcim, also<br />

Axpo encourages the diffusion <strong>of</strong> best practices across the firm to add value. Know-


Case Studies<br />

how is being shared, however, mostly within Axpo's subunits, respectively is being<br />

spread to the units through corporate parent. Compared to the other two case objects,<br />

Axpo probably has more possibilities to ensure st<strong>and</strong>ardisation <strong>of</strong> certain processes<br />

than FZ or Holcim, as it is mostly operating within the same regulatory space <strong>and</strong> is<br />

obliged to the same regulatory bodies on a national level. This concentration <strong>of</strong><br />

production activities also make its lobbying activities very effective, <strong>and</strong> gives it a<br />

critical mass in the Swiss market, which has effects on its negotiation strength for new<br />

projects. Compared to smaller firms, synergies from multi-site activities therefore arise<br />

from its balanced energy mix - i.e. its engagement in different types <strong>of</strong> power<br />

production, with significant advantages for its plants' utilisation <strong>and</strong> revenue<br />

generation - from cost savings through central support activities, reduced corporate<br />

risk, <strong>and</strong> from more resources to engage in R&D <strong>and</strong> new business development<br />

strategies, just to name a few.<br />

FZ's industry <strong>and</strong> organisational set-up probably are the most challenging <strong>of</strong> the three<br />

case objects in respect <strong>of</strong> multi-site value creation. For comparison, due to the nature<br />

<strong>of</strong> its industry, FZ can only limitedly st<strong>and</strong>ardise key processes across its portfolio.<br />

With regard to the aviation-side, each <strong>and</strong> every airport has a unique topographical<br />

l<strong>and</strong>scape in which it is embedded, requiring equally unique l<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>and</strong> departure<br />

systems, as well as designs for its civil engineering works. Thus, although industry<br />

regulation for airports is probably more globally harmonised than in the other two<br />

industries, being based on ICAO st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>and</strong> recommended practices, the<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> these regulations on an individual site requires tailored adaptation.<br />

On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the operational <strong>and</strong> commercial management <strong>of</strong> terminals allow a<br />

high degree <strong>of</strong> process st<strong>and</strong>ardisation. Equally, synergies <strong>and</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ardisations may be<br />

achieved in the selection <strong>of</strong> various third parties with regard to airport services (such<br />

as ground h<strong>and</strong>ling or catering) <strong>and</strong> commerce (e.g. food <strong>and</strong> beverage, retail <strong>and</strong> duty<br />

free). Since FZ has the relevant best practice know-how from its Zurich operation,<br />

which it combines with its capability for adaptation to the local environment, it creates<br />

value across its operations mostly through the transfer <strong>of</strong> know-how. In its Latin<br />

American operations, however, it has additional possibilities to realise synergies from<br />

the combined management <strong>of</strong> airport clusters through its joint venture A-Port, as<br />

illustrated by its Honduras operations. Furthermore, A-Port is able to centralise certain<br />

planning functions across the Latin American portfolio, along with a rotation <strong>of</strong> its<br />

airport managers across the portfolio airports <strong>and</strong> a more intense exchange between the<br />

individual airports. Concluding, FZ will probably never be able to achieve the intensity<br />

<strong>of</strong> inter-unit exchange <strong>of</strong> the other two case objects, Holcim <strong>and</strong> Axpo, since it only<br />

323


324<br />

Case Studies<br />

engages as a minority investor cum management contract in its airports. Nevertheless,<br />

the firm is in the process <strong>of</strong> intensifying interaction between its airport managers also<br />

across the different parts <strong>of</strong> the world, to better exploit its expertise.<br />

Comparing the value creation endeavours <strong>of</strong> our three location-dependent case objects<br />

in single- <strong>and</strong> multi-site settings confirms, that they mostly pursue similar synergy <strong>and</strong><br />

cost saving opportunities, albeit with partly different intensity <strong>and</strong> focus. Table 5-14<br />

provides an overview <strong>of</strong> the identified fields <strong>of</strong> value creation in multi-site operations,<br />

<strong>and</strong> their significance for each case object.


Case Studies<br />

Fields <strong>of</strong> value creation - multi-site perspective Axpo FZ Holcim<br />

Relations<br />

Resources<br />

Institutions<br />

Signalling on the basis <strong>of</strong> reputation & identity �� �� ��<br />

facilitation <strong>of</strong> market entry �� �� ��<br />

acceleration <strong>of</strong> the local unit's embedding process �� � ��<br />

increase in credibility <strong>and</strong> status <strong>of</strong> local unit �� �� ��<br />

Institutional & cultural sensitivity � �� ��<br />

lower local transaction costs, faster time to implementation �� � ��<br />

increased managerial effectiveness � �� ��<br />

increased bargaining power � � ��<br />

Knowledge resources & best practice synergies �� �� ��<br />

improved overall productivity � �� ��<br />

improved safety <strong>and</strong> reliability �� �� ��<br />

common underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> key processes <strong>and</strong> firm approach � � ��<br />

Corporate management synergies ~ �� ��<br />

better leverage <strong>of</strong> entrepreneurial activities ~ � ~<br />

better fit <strong>of</strong> local unit's organisational design with local<br />

requirements<br />

~ �� ��<br />

strategic priority-setting <strong>and</strong> funding <strong>of</strong> projects with<br />

highest expected returns<br />

� �� ��<br />

Financial synergies �� � ��<br />

reduced corporate risk �� � ��<br />

advantages <strong>of</strong> an internal capital market (fin. holdings) �� � ��<br />

tax advantages (financial holdings) � ~ �<br />

financial economies <strong>of</strong> scale (financial holdings) � � �<br />

Compliance monitoring � � ��<br />

reduced risk <strong>of</strong> costs <strong>of</strong> non-compliance <strong>and</strong> negative<br />

reputation spillovers<br />

� � ��<br />

lower transaction costs (particularly with public stakeh.) �� � ��<br />

accumulation <strong>of</strong> institutional assets �� �� ��<br />

Political support & regulatory lobbying acc. to spatial scale �� � ��<br />

lower transaction costs with public stakeholders �� �� ��<br />

increased effectiveness <strong>of</strong> firm's political activities on<br />

various spatial scales<br />

�� � ��<br />

increased bargaining power towards public stakeholders �� ~ �<br />

�� high significance; � significance; ~ low significance; � no significance<br />

Table 5-14: Fields <strong>of</strong> multi-site value creation <strong>and</strong> their significance for case objects<br />

325


326<br />

Case Studies<br />

5.4.5 Summary & conclusion<br />

<strong>The</strong> comparison <strong>of</strong> our case objects along the dimensions <strong>of</strong> the research framework<br />

has revealed similarities in local exposure <strong>and</strong> in their embedding strategies to balance<br />

such exposure. Particularly notable is difference between Axpo, FZ <strong>and</strong> Holcim in<br />

their ownership structure, with consequent effects also on their entrepreneurial<br />

freedom. While Holcim - as a fully privately owned firm - is able to pursue its<br />

business strategy without any firm-specific public policy restrictions, Axpo <strong>and</strong> FZ<br />

have to fulfil a public mission, which has priority before any other business<br />

development endeavours. Moreover, FZ is constrained in its local development<br />

opportunities by a public policy framework which balances the regional economic<br />

interests <strong>of</strong> a growing airport with the population's interests in high quality <strong>of</strong> life <strong>and</strong><br />

in environmental protection. However, the interviewed representatives <strong>of</strong> Axpo <strong>and</strong> FZ<br />

are convinced that as long as their firm performs according to its mission, it is not<br />

significantly constrained in its expansion strategy.<br />

<strong>The</strong> embedding capabilities <strong>of</strong> the three firms most significantly differ with regard to<br />

their degree <strong>of</strong> structure <strong>and</strong> international harmonisation. Holcim centrally guides its<br />

country organisations in respect <strong>of</strong> corporate social responsibility programmes <strong>and</strong> the<br />

establishment <strong>of</strong> continuous stakeholder dialogues. On the issue <strong>of</strong> lobbying the firm<br />

transparently communicates its lobbying resources, which it uses on a supra-national<br />

level, but also within the respective countries <strong>of</strong> operation. Similarly, but on a<br />

geographically smaller scale, Axpo engages in lobbying activities on its holding level,<br />

allowing it to exert more influence on regulatory developments in its home market<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong>. However, embedding activities on a local scale are decentralised <strong>and</strong> the<br />

corporate parent does not prescribe any specific approach or activities to be taken. <strong>The</strong><br />

least structured approach, due to a different organisational set-up, is taken by FZ,<br />

which supports the airports in its portfolio with regard to political <strong>and</strong> regulatory<br />

issues on a need-basis, respectively pays courtesy visits to important decision-makers<br />

from time to time, but leaves the embedding approach <strong>and</strong> respective activities fully to<br />

its local airport management.<br />

With regard to single-site value creation, we could illustrate that all case objects create<br />

value by means <strong>of</strong> their embedding capabilities on similar dimensions. <strong>The</strong> most<br />

important fields <strong>of</strong> value creation are transaction cost savings, increased operational<br />

efficiency, <strong>and</strong> the valorisation <strong>of</strong> by-products. Through their embedding capabilities<br />

all three firms are able to lower their transaction costs from their interactions with<br />

public stakeholders, in particular local administrations <strong>and</strong> the regulator, but also due


Case Studies<br />

to fewer litigation cases with the local community. For FZ, these savings are best<br />

illustrated through its international projects, as the situation in its Zurich operation is<br />

influenced by many factors which it cannot influence by means <strong>of</strong> local embedding.<br />

Holcim has made very good experiences with its approach to stakeholder dialogues,<br />

being able to take up <strong>and</strong> resolve issues before any hardening <strong>of</strong> minds, with <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

costly consequences. <strong>The</strong> same applies to Axpo, which establishes good working<br />

relationships with stakeholders in project planning phases <strong>and</strong> consequently maintains<br />

closeness with the local community throughout its concession phase. All three firms<br />

are able to improve their operational efficiency, be it through the opportunity to better<br />

exploit existing resources, e.g. due to good labour relations which lower plant<br />

downtimes, as in the case <strong>of</strong> Holcim; or on the basis <strong>of</strong> longer shop opening hours, or<br />

procedural improvements to increase runway utilisation, as in the case <strong>of</strong> Zurich<br />

Airport; or as a result <strong>of</strong> the possibility to serially connect multiple hydropower plants,<br />

as in the case <strong>of</strong> Axpo. <strong>The</strong> third important field <strong>of</strong> value creation on the basis <strong>of</strong> local<br />

embedding is the valorisation <strong>of</strong> by-products <strong>of</strong> our case objects. While Axpo <strong>and</strong><br />

Holcim predominantly are able to economically exploit produced heat (e.g. district<br />

heating or CO2 storage for biomass production), FZ is able to economise the fact that<br />

it channels large numbers <strong>of</strong> travellers <strong>and</strong> other groups through its infrastructure<br />

daily. In addition, Holcim's use <strong>of</strong> AFR materials for its kiln operation is a splendid<br />

example how it 'CO2-neutrally' exploits the externalities <strong>of</strong> other industries. Many <strong>of</strong><br />

these activities have become possible due to the firms' high organisational legitimacy<br />

with its local stakeholders, which allowed them to draw on accumulated enabling<br />

assets to obtain the necessary approvals for implementation.<br />

In line with the constraints <strong>of</strong> location-fixity, the multi-site creation <strong>of</strong> value<br />

predominantly results from intangible resources. <strong>The</strong> traditional fields <strong>of</strong> financial<br />

synergy realisation, pursued by most major MNCs, are also relevant for Holcim <strong>and</strong><br />

Axpo - which are organised as financial holdings - but do only insignificantly apply to<br />

Zurich Airport. More importantly, however, all three firms create value through their<br />

monitoring <strong>and</strong> control <strong>of</strong> their portfolio members' regulatory compliance, including<br />

their efforts to increase overall transparency. <strong>The</strong>se efforts are complemented by the<br />

political support <strong>and</strong> lobbying which the firms centrally provide to their subsidiaries.<br />

Less seizable, all three case objects create value through their reputation, which serves<br />

to signal positive attributes from the parent company to the local market. Equally their<br />

ability to adapt to the local environment, while transferring know-how from the<br />

corporate centre has positive impacts on their transaction costs with the local<br />

stakeholders <strong>and</strong> the time to implementation <strong>of</strong> business development endeavours. On<br />

327


328<br />

Case Studies<br />

the other h<strong>and</strong>, all three firms create value through the realisation <strong>of</strong> best practice<br />

synergies with regard to production, safety <strong>and</strong> reliability, <strong>and</strong> with the objective to<br />

attain a common underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> key processes <strong>and</strong> business philosophy. Again,<br />

Holcim pursues such best practice exchange with support from its central HGRS unit<br />

<strong>and</strong> within its country clusters, while Axpo focuses on a few selected fields within<br />

which the holding engages, <strong>and</strong> ultimately FZ identifies areas to leverage its airports'<br />

capabilities <strong>of</strong> on a case-by-case basis.<br />

Overall, the assessment <strong>of</strong> the case objects' embedding capabilities <strong>and</strong> the related<br />

effects on value creation suggest, that despite the limitations in synergy realisation<br />

from value-chain optimisations, location-fixed firms have significant opportunities to<br />

create value. Not surprisingly, most <strong>of</strong> these are based on intangible resources, in<br />

particular the transfer <strong>of</strong> best-practice know-how. However, in addition to these<br />

intangibles, Holcim also found ways to economise on joint procurement or the<br />

management <strong>of</strong> critical <strong>and</strong> expensive spare parts across larger geographies, due to its<br />

size <strong>and</strong> its widespread geographical presence. We therefore conclude, that large<br />

location-fixed MNC's or firms with geographically clustered markets are able to<br />

realise a number <strong>of</strong> conventional operational synergies in spite <strong>of</strong> their spatial<br />

immobility.


Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

6 Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

<strong>The</strong> intention <strong>of</strong> this dissertation was to underst<strong>and</strong> the particular characteristics <strong>and</strong><br />

circumstances <strong>of</strong> our research object, the utility <strong>and</strong> concession-based firm, pertaining<br />

to its location-fixity <strong>and</strong> the latter's effects on value creation. We segregated our<br />

research topic into two main parts: (1) the investigation <strong>of</strong> location-fixity from a<br />

single-site perspective, addressed by the research questions one to four; <strong>and</strong> (2) based<br />

on these insights, the further analysis <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> value creation in a multisite<br />

setting, which is covered by the research questions five <strong>and</strong> six. <strong>The</strong>reby, our first<br />

research question aimed at developing an underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> its<br />

constituting elements, the resulting firm dependence, <strong>and</strong> the external moderators to<br />

location-fixity. Research question two addressed the effects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity on the<br />

UCF <strong>and</strong> the thereto related institutional exposure, with the aim to conceptualise the<br />

latter <strong>and</strong> to identify its sources. Furthermore, it was the intention to gain insights on<br />

the general limitations <strong>and</strong> the opportunities that institutional exposure involves. <strong>The</strong><br />

third research question concerned the effects <strong>of</strong> local exposure - the combined effect<br />

<strong>of</strong> location-fixity <strong>and</strong> institutional exposure - on the UCF's value creation<br />

opportunities. With research question four we turned towards identifying the<br />

moderators to the relation between location-fixity <strong>and</strong> value creation. In this context,<br />

we analysed what kind <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities UCFs need in order to mitigate the<br />

effects <strong>of</strong> local exposure in value-enhancing ways. With research question five we<br />

shifted our attention to a multi-site perspective, assessing how location-fixity impacts<br />

UCFs' resource management across their sites. Ultimately, in research question six we<br />

dealt with the possibilities for multi-unit UCF to create value under the conditions <strong>of</strong><br />

location-fixity <strong>and</strong> local exposure. In conclusion, the present chapter will discuss the<br />

theoretical <strong>and</strong> practical implications for firms with location-fixed assets.<br />

329


330<br />

Research question Sub-chapter reference<br />

1. Conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> location-fixity sub-chapter 4.5 <strong>Location</strong>-fixity<br />

2. <strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> location-fixity &<br />

institutional exposure on UCF<br />

3. <strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> local exposure on value<br />

creation<br />

4. Mitigation <strong>of</strong> limitations from<br />

location-fixity / local exposure<br />

5. Impact <strong>of</strong> location-fixity on multi-unit<br />

UCF resource management<br />

Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

sub-chapter 4.6 Institutional exposure (particularly<br />

section 4.6.4 Institutional exposure by identified<br />

stakeholder group)<br />

sub-chapter 4.8 Embedding capabilities <strong>of</strong> local<br />

management<br />

sub-chapters 4.8 Embedding capabilities <strong>of</strong> local<br />

management; 4.9 Value creation<br />

section 4.10.3 Limitations to multiple unit firms within<br />

UCI<br />

6. Multi-unit value creation <strong>of</strong> UCF sections 4.10.5 UCF value creation in multi-site<br />

operations; 4.10.6 Relational dimension; 4.10.7<br />

Resource dimension; 4.10.8 Institutional dimension;<br />

4.10.9 Summary<br />

7. <strong>The</strong>oretical <strong>and</strong> practical implications sub-chapters 6.2 <strong>and</strong> following<br />

Table 6-1: Overview on research questions <strong>and</strong> relevant sub-chapters reference<br />

Before we exp<strong>and</strong> on the implications <strong>of</strong> our research, we will briefly summarise the<br />

objectives <strong>and</strong> core elements <strong>of</strong> the preceding chapters. In chapter one, we started by<br />

framing the research problem <strong>of</strong> the utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based firm regarding its<br />

location-fixity <strong>and</strong> the thereto related effects on value creation. In this context, we<br />

outlined the existing research gap <strong>and</strong> proceeded by highlighting the theoretical <strong>and</strong><br />

practical relevance <strong>of</strong> the research topic <strong>and</strong> by formulating our guiding research<br />

questions.<br />

In chapter two, we identified the theoretical fields relevant to our framework<br />

development. As our research is based on a multi-lens approach, we aimed to briefly<br />

introduce the main fields <strong>of</strong> research <strong>and</strong> their core concepts on which we have drawn<br />

in our research framework. Accordingly, we covered the fields <strong>of</strong> strategic<br />

management research, economic geography, (new) institutionalism, <strong>and</strong> economic<br />

sociology. As we employed a grounded theory approach, our purpose was not to<br />

delineate our research within the literature review. Rather, we intended to openmindedly<br />

carve out the relevant aspects <strong>and</strong> to familiarise ourselves <strong>and</strong> the reader<br />

with notions <strong>and</strong> definitions to which we have returned throughout our empirical<br />

chapter four.


Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

<strong>The</strong> third chapter expounded our approach to the empirical part <strong>of</strong> our research. We<br />

argued why our research topic suggests an inductive approach, attributing it to theorybuilding<br />

research. Furthermore, we clarified our research paradigm, the employed<br />

methodology, <strong>and</strong> illustrated our research design. We substantiated the underlying<br />

reasons for choosing grounded theory methodology to approach our research topic,<br />

why we decided for case research, <strong>and</strong> how we purposefully selected the case study<br />

objects. In addition, we have attached great importance to the issues <strong>of</strong> research<br />

quality, making transparent our procedures <strong>and</strong> the employed measures throughout our<br />

empirical research, in order to ensure high validity <strong>and</strong> reliability with regard to our<br />

results.<br />

Chapter four represents the core <strong>of</strong> our dissertation. <strong>The</strong>rein we have developed a<br />

comprehensive research framework <strong>and</strong> according propositions as a response to our<br />

research questions. We started with a conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> the location-fixity construct,<br />

central to our research topic, whose characteristics are summarised in Table 4-2. Based<br />

on the latter, we continued with the elaboration <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure, which is<br />

directly related to the degree <strong>of</strong> the firm's location-fixity. After outlining a typology<br />

for the UCF's stakeholders, where we importantly distinguish between public <strong>and</strong><br />

private stakeholders, we have broken down the meaning <strong>and</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> institutional<br />

exposure to each individual stakeholder type. Subsequently, we turned our attention to<br />

the moderators <strong>of</strong> the firm's institutional exposure. <strong>The</strong> insights from our case study<br />

research have indicated two moderators, i.e. the local economic relevance <strong>of</strong> the firm<br />

<strong>and</strong> the firm's competitive environment. Interestingly, while there are strong<br />

indications that the latter is <strong>of</strong> relevance, the statements which we collected in our<br />

interviews remained ambiguous, which led us to briefly elaborate on the juxtaposing<br />

explanations <strong>and</strong> to develop propositions for the rivalling options, ultimately<br />

commending the issue to further research. In accordance with the structure <strong>of</strong> the<br />

research framework, we further developed the notion <strong>of</strong> embeddedness <strong>and</strong><br />

organisational legitimacy, before continuing with the definition <strong>of</strong> the firm's<br />

embedding capabilities, which are considered as moderators to the firm's local<br />

exposure. <strong>The</strong>reby, we have identified two groups <strong>of</strong> capabilities: structural<br />

(economic) embedding capabilities, which include all tangible activities that manifest<br />

the firm's commitment to its location beyond symbolic actions; <strong>and</strong> relational (social)<br />

embedding capabilities, which relate to the firm's activities in building relational <strong>and</strong><br />

reputational assets towards institutional isomorphism. <strong>The</strong>se embedding capabilities<br />

are condensed <strong>and</strong> defined in section 4.8.6. In the last thematic block within the singlesite<br />

perspective we concentrated on value creation, first outlining our underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong><br />

331


332<br />

Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

value. On this basis, we continued identifying the value creating dimensions for UCFs<br />

under conditions <strong>of</strong> local exposure. Consequently, we have developed the construct <strong>of</strong><br />

enabling assets, which are defined as idiosyncratic intangible resources that the firm<br />

accumulates over time with its stakeholders, as an insurance against unforeseeable<br />

events <strong>and</strong> as facilitators in its business development. <strong>The</strong> relevant dimensions <strong>of</strong><br />

value creation include strategic options, risk decrease, <strong>and</strong> short-term value creation,<br />

which are summarised in section 4.9.5.<br />

<strong>The</strong> second part <strong>of</strong> our research framework is concerned with a multiple site<br />

perspective on the UCF. Its considerations significantly build on the insights <strong>and</strong><br />

conceptualisations <strong>of</strong> the first part. We started with a brief description <strong>of</strong> the role <strong>of</strong> the<br />

corporate parent <strong>and</strong> linkage-formation in strategic management research.<br />

Subsequently we outlined, why the value creation opportunities are somewhat limited<br />

for location-fixed firms, particularly in respect <strong>of</strong> UCFs, before proceeding with<br />

aspects <strong>of</strong> value for UCFs' multi-unit operations. In our research framework we<br />

identified three relevant dimensions <strong>of</strong> value creation, which we consequently<br />

elaborated: relations, resources, <strong>and</strong> institutions. Finally, the value creation effects in<br />

multiple unit operations have been summarised in section 4.10.9. Where appropriate,<br />

we have illustrated aspects <strong>of</strong> the framework with examples from our empirical<br />

research.<br />

In order to support the developed research framework with empirical insights, in<br />

chapter five we presented the condensed findings from our case study research. After a<br />

brief introduction to each case study object <strong>and</strong> to its industry, we followed again the<br />

logic <strong>of</strong> our research framework, illustrating the relevance <strong>of</strong> our findings for each<br />

construct with examples <strong>and</strong> embedded cases. Thus, we empirically elaborated how<br />

the case study objects create value on the dimensions <strong>of</strong> the framework, despite their<br />

particular characteristics <strong>of</strong> the UCF. After an individual discussion <strong>of</strong> the three case<br />

studies, we have immersed into a cross-case comparison with the objective to<br />

underline similarities across industries (external validity), <strong>and</strong> to identify <strong>and</strong> explain<br />

essential differences in our findings.<br />

<strong>The</strong> implications from our insights in the chapters four <strong>and</strong> five will be the subject <strong>of</strong><br />

the present chapter six. Subsequently, we will discuss the research's contributions for<br />

theory <strong>and</strong> practice, its limitations, <strong>and</strong> the thereto related recommendations for future<br />

research.


Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

6.1 Summary <strong>of</strong> propositions<br />

<strong>The</strong> following propositions (P) have been derived throughout our research. Figure 6-1<br />

illustrates how they relate to the research framework.<br />

embedding<br />

capabilities<br />

local exposure from<br />

moderate P2<br />

location fixity value creation<br />

influences<br />

P7<br />

location fixity P3-P6<br />

strategic options<br />

local econom.<br />

relevance <strong>of</strong> firm<br />

competitive<br />

environment<br />

business risks<br />

P11-12<br />

P1<br />

P8-P10<br />

institutional exposure<br />

operational<br />

Figure 6-1: Overview on derived propositions <strong>and</strong> affiliation with research framework<br />

P13-14<br />

P15-16<br />

P18-19<br />

With the exception <strong>of</strong> proposition two, the first six propositions relate exclusively to<br />

location-fixity, respectively to its impact on the firm's institutional exposure:<br />

Proposition 1. <strong>The</strong> higher a firm's location-fixity, the higher its institutional exposure <strong>and</strong> risk <strong>of</strong> rent<br />

appropriation by its local stakeholders.<br />

Proposition 2. <strong>The</strong> potential negative impact <strong>of</strong> local exposure on the firm's value creation is<br />

moderated by its capabilities to embed itself locally.<br />

Proposition 3. <strong>The</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> location-fixity is determined through a firm's dependence on locationbound<br />

resources which are exclusive <strong>and</strong> scarce in supply.<br />

Proposition 4. <strong>The</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> location-fixity is determined through a firm's long-term commitment to a<br />

location with regard to capital <strong>and</strong> assets (sunk costs).<br />

Proposition 5. <strong>The</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> location-fixity is determined through a need to be geographically close to<br />

the customer, due to the nature <strong>of</strong> the product for some UCF.<br />

Proposition 6. <strong>The</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> location-fixity is also determined by the ownership structure <strong>of</strong> the firm,<br />

when the owner pursues public policy objectives, or if his utility function in general incorporates<br />

factors other than pr<strong>of</strong>it-seeking.<br />

<strong>The</strong> propositions seven to ten address the moderators between location-fixity <strong>and</strong><br />

institutional exposure, including the rivalling propositions on the moderating role <strong>of</strong><br />

the firm's competitive environment:<br />

Proposition 7. <strong>The</strong> institutional exposure <strong>of</strong> the UCF is moderated by its role <strong>and</strong> importance within<br />

the local economy, on the basis <strong>of</strong> its industry nature or its contribution to the local livelihood.<br />

Proposition 8. Institutional exposure decreases in an environment with local competitors, if the UCF<br />

cooperates with competitors with regard to stakeholder issues <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

333


334<br />

Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

Proposition 9. Institutional exposure decreases in an environment with local competitors, because<br />

industry-specific externalities originate from several industry players, which reduces incentives to<br />

dispraise a single firm.<br />

Proposition 10. A high level <strong>of</strong> competition leads to an increase in institutional exposure, due to<br />

stakeholders' possibility to play competing firms <strong>of</strong>f against each other.<br />

<strong>The</strong> next two propositions are concerned with institutional exposure:<br />

Proposition 11. <strong>The</strong> lower (higher) the firm's appropriable rent, the lower (higher) is its institutional<br />

exposure.<br />

Proposition 12. <strong>The</strong> higher the firm's institutional exposure, the more its organisational embedding<br />

matters with regard to its value creation opportunities <strong>and</strong> long-term success.<br />

<strong>The</strong> remaining propositions 13 to 19 relate to the firm's embedding capabilities <strong>and</strong> the<br />

framework's dimensions <strong>of</strong> value creation:<br />

Proposition 13. <strong>The</strong> effective use <strong>of</strong> the UCF's embedding capabilities leads to an accumulation <strong>of</strong><br />

enabling assets, which help the firm to master unexpected threatening events faster, less costly <strong>and</strong><br />

with less damage.<br />

Proposition 14. <strong>The</strong> creation <strong>and</strong> accumulation <strong>of</strong> enabling assets allows UCFs to shorten their time to<br />

implementation for major infrastructure-related investments, as well as other business development<br />

activities.<br />

Proposition 15. <strong>The</strong> UCF's effective use <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities creates value by reducing the risk<br />

<strong>of</strong> unfavourable regulatory <strong>and</strong> political discretion.<br />

Proposition 16. By effectively employing its embedding capabilities, the UCF is able to reduce the<br />

risk to not recover its sunk costs, respectively to increase the probability <strong>of</strong> capital recovery.<br />

Proposition 17. <strong>The</strong> higher the firm's organisational legitimacy, <strong>and</strong> the more credibly it is able to<br />

convey its readiness to search for integrative solutions, the higher the approval by its stakeholders for,<br />

respectively the lower the resistance against its endeavours to improve efficiency.<br />

Proposition 18. <strong>The</strong> UCF's degree <strong>of</strong> local embeddedness <strong>and</strong> organisational legitimacy indirectly<br />

influence its value creation by increasing the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> its financial processes.<br />

Proposition 19. <strong>The</strong> UCF’s effective use <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities creates value by increasing the<br />

firm's resource efficiency through joint exploitation <strong>of</strong> positive externalities or the transformation <strong>of</strong><br />

negative externalities into exploitable ones.<br />

In the following sub-chapters we turn to the theoretical <strong>and</strong> practical implications <strong>of</strong><br />

our findings.<br />

6.2 Contributions to theory<br />

By means <strong>of</strong> this dissertation we have contributed to theory building in a number <strong>of</strong><br />

related research fields, most notably through the conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> location-fixity


Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

<strong>and</strong> the identification <strong>of</strong> its effects on firms' value creation opportunities, as well as the<br />

identification <strong>of</strong> value-enhancing embedding capabilities for UCFs. We will<br />

subsequently discuss the results' theoretical contributions <strong>and</strong> how they relate to the<br />

relevant research lenses.<br />

6.2.1 Conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> location-fixity<br />

Among the central contributions <strong>of</strong> this dissertation is the conceptualisation <strong>of</strong><br />

location-fixity from a firm perspective, thus increasing definitional clarity <strong>of</strong> an<br />

important notion within economic geography. While existing definitions in the field<br />

strongly focus on individual aspects <strong>of</strong> location-fixity, such as resource-dependence<br />

(e.g. Oinas, 1998), locality-specific social relations (e.g. Cox & Mair, 1988), or the<br />

facilitation <strong>of</strong> a trading relationship (e.g. Lamminmaki, 2005; OE Williamson, 1991),<br />

we have aimed at an integration <strong>of</strong> these different views <strong>and</strong> aspects. Consequently,<br />

we view location-fixity from the angles <strong>of</strong> resource-dependence (upstream), marketdependence<br />

(downstream), <strong>and</strong> the additional aspect <strong>of</strong> ownership-dependence, which<br />

is <strong>of</strong> particular importance for our research object, as the state in many cases is<br />

involved as a (partial) owner. With the locally embedded firm as our unit <strong>of</strong> analysis,<br />

our concept <strong>of</strong> location-fixity adds to a lesser used perspective in economic geography,<br />

which commonly argues from higher scale geographies, such as regions or countries,<br />

respectively clusters <strong>and</strong> networks <strong>of</strong> firms (Oinas, 1997). Thus, our segregation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

sources <strong>of</strong> location-fixity on the firm-level may add another analytical lens for<br />

assessing the economic impacts <strong>of</strong> spatial immobility.<br />

<strong>The</strong> definition <strong>of</strong> location-fixity might contribute too to the field <strong>of</strong> strategic<br />

management research, stressing the relevance <strong>of</strong> the spatial dimension for economic<br />

actors <strong>and</strong> extending the notion <strong>of</strong> asset specificity through addition <strong>of</strong> a spatial<br />

dimension. When the concepts <strong>of</strong> asset fixity <strong>and</strong> specificity were originally<br />

developed, space was not explicitly considered. Ward & Hite (1999) therefore suggest<br />

the addition <strong>of</strong> the notion <strong>of</strong> spatial fixity, which arises because there is a cost to<br />

moving a firm's productive assets. Our concept <strong>of</strong> location-fixity strengthens this<br />

stance.<br />

In addition, the three identified dimensions <strong>of</strong> location-fixity might - in combination<br />

with the characteristics <strong>of</strong> UCF - provide an interesting lens on the concept <strong>of</strong> mobility<br />

barriers, understood as deterrents <strong>of</strong> movement between groups because <strong>of</strong> related<br />

substantial costs, a significant lapse <strong>of</strong> time, or uncertainty about the outcome (McGee<br />

& Thomas, 1986). We suggest that a location-fix UCF is able to erect strong mobility<br />

barriers on the basis <strong>of</strong> its local dependence <strong>and</strong> embeddedness. On one h<strong>and</strong>, its sunk<br />

335


336<br />

Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

cost characteristics <strong>and</strong> resulting subadditive cost functions would induce it to remain<br />

in business, as long as its operating costs are covered - even if its rents do not cover its<br />

long-run average costs - thus deterring potential competitors. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, it<br />

owns a valuable scarce resource in the form <strong>of</strong> a concession, <strong>and</strong> provides a good<br />

which is <strong>of</strong> critical relevance to the local economy. Similar arguments apply for the<br />

ownership-dimension <strong>of</strong> location-fixity. <strong>The</strong> UCF thus enjoys strong shields against<br />

competition <strong>and</strong> is protected through a local interest in its going concern <strong>and</strong><br />

sustainable livelihood.<br />

6.2.2 Conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure<br />

Institutional exposure essentially draws on notions from stakeholder <strong>and</strong> institutional<br />

theory. Stakeholder theory, on one h<strong>and</strong>, predominantly views stakeholders <strong>and</strong> their<br />

interests as contingencies that management must respect <strong>and</strong> balance in their variety.<br />

<strong>The</strong>reby, one <strong>of</strong> the major determinants <strong>of</strong> stakeholder salience is their power in<br />

relation to the firm (e.g. de Bakker & den Hond, 2008; Hill & Jones, 1992; Mitchell et<br />

al., 1997): Based on the relevance <strong>of</strong> the firm's various stakeholders, corporate<br />

management decides on the strategic priorities to pursue (Müller-Stewens & Lechner,<br />

2005). Institutional theory, on the other h<strong>and</strong>, is more concerned with the organisation<br />

as an adaptable social system, <strong>and</strong> how these values <strong>and</strong> cultural norms influence its<br />

activity, in particular how they control the behaviour <strong>and</strong> activities <strong>of</strong> individuals<br />

within organisations (Zucker, 1977). <strong>The</strong> notion <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure fuses both<br />

perspectives: it acknowledges the influence <strong>of</strong> the external environment on the firm's<br />

values <strong>and</strong> norms, as well as on its behaviour, <strong>and</strong> st<strong>and</strong>s for a stakeholder's aggregate<br />

potential to negatively impact the firm, which is the central criterion <strong>of</strong> stakeholder<br />

salience from a strategic perspective. By underst<strong>and</strong>ing institutional exposure as the<br />

degree, to which a firm is exposed <strong>and</strong> vulnerable to local stakeholders' claims,<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> expectations, we provide a theoretical construct to represent, what<br />

instrumental stakeholder theory aims to mitigate. <strong>The</strong>reby, we include the potential<br />

effects if the firm loses its organisational legitimacy with (some <strong>of</strong>) its stakeholders,<br />

thus not only relating to the firm's vulnerability with regard to stakeholder activities,<br />

but also to potential indirect harm from the loss <strong>of</strong> passive stakeholder support.<br />

Furthermore, in developing the construct <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure construct we have<br />

assessed <strong>and</strong> contextualised the various roles <strong>of</strong> the public stakeholders (cf. section<br />

4.6.4). In so doing, we contribute to a better underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the multiple roles that<br />

the State combines, <strong>and</strong> the resulting potential conflicts <strong>of</strong> interest pertaining to the<br />

UCF. This conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> sovereign <strong>and</strong> political influences on the firm <strong>and</strong> the


Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

resulting hazards provides an interesting lens on the firm’s relations with its public<br />

stakeholders, combining notions from TCE, new institutionalism, public policy <strong>and</strong><br />

political science.<br />

6.2.3 Identification <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities as value-creating factor<br />

By having determined the traits <strong>and</strong> characteristics <strong>of</strong> the firm's embedding capabilities<br />

with regard to value creation, this dissertation adds to strategic management literature,<br />

which to date has only selectively adopted the concept <strong>of</strong> embeddedness. More<br />

precisely, the latter's application in the past remained mostly limited to issues <strong>of</strong><br />

network embeddedness (e.g. Gnyawali & Madhavan, 2001; Uzzi, 1996) - to some<br />

extent also considering performance implications (e.g. Gulati et al., 2000), relational<br />

embeddedness in dyadic relationships (e.g. Dyer & Singh, 1998; Lavie, 2007), or the<br />

institutional <strong>and</strong> cultural obstacles to local embedding to MNE subsidiaries (e.g.<br />

Rugman & Verbeke, 2001).<br />

Our theoretical contribution therefore is tw<strong>of</strong>old: On one side, (1) we stress the<br />

importance <strong>of</strong> business context with regard to a firm's value creation. We thus<br />

theoretically valorise the firm's relations with its local environment, <strong>and</strong> its<br />

embeddedness therein, within strategic management research (evidently under<br />

consideration <strong>of</strong> our findings' limited applicability to UCF, whereas a wider<br />

generalisability would need to be tested). Thus, we are linking a key notion from<br />

institutional research lenses with strategic management research's focus on rentseeking.<br />

On the other h<strong>and</strong>, (2) we added insights with regard to the specific activities<br />

<strong>and</strong> capabilities which are needed to foster local embedding. By identifying <strong>and</strong><br />

conceptualising relevant firm capabilities with regard to local embedding <strong>and</strong><br />

establishing a link to value creation, we have contributed to the integration <strong>of</strong> spatial<br />

embeddedness into strategic management research. Particularly with regard to the<br />

relational view <strong>of</strong> the firm, we have empirically supported the notion that<br />

embeddedness with the local environment, the firm's organisational legitimacy, its<br />

reputation <strong>and</strong> trust represent valuable resources, which may contribute to competitive<br />

advantage.<br />

6.2.4 Enabling assets - linking institutional <strong>and</strong> strategic approaches<br />

Related to our conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> the firm's embedding capabilities, we developed<br />

the construct <strong>of</strong> enabling assets, theoretically situated at the crossings between<br />

institutional <strong>and</strong> strategic management theory. Defined as idiosyncratic intangible<br />

resources which the firm accumulates over time with its stakeholders, as an insurance<br />

337


338<br />

Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

against unforeseeable events <strong>and</strong> as facilitators in its business development, the<br />

construct contributes to the relational view within strategic management. More<br />

precisely, enabling assets extend the notion <strong>of</strong> relation-specific assets, as they reach<br />

beyond inter-firm relations (Dyer & Singh, 1998) to create relational rents <strong>and</strong> to<br />

lower transaction costs.<br />

Moreover, the construct <strong>of</strong> enabling assets also contributes to institutional theory,<br />

complementing the existing concept <strong>of</strong> relational assets (Dunning, 2002), which are<br />

defined as “the stock <strong>of</strong> a firm's willingness <strong>and</strong> capability to access, shape <strong>and</strong> engage<br />

in economically beneficial relationships” (ibid.: 572). First <strong>of</strong> all, enabling assets do<br />

not refer to the firm's willingness or capability, but are the result <strong>of</strong> such capabilities<br />

<strong>and</strong> efforts. <strong>The</strong>y represent the outcome <strong>of</strong> the firm's activities towards embedding <strong>and</strong><br />

organisational legitimacy, which includes the social aspects <strong>of</strong> trust <strong>and</strong> reputationbuilding,<br />

but also the structural aspects <strong>of</strong> good self-governance <strong>and</strong> the<br />

compensation 171 <strong>of</strong> stakeholders for the negative effects on their welfare through the<br />

firm's externalities.<br />

Furthermore, in contrast to Dunning's (ibid.: 572) rather open reference to<br />

“economically beneficial relationships”, enabling assets point to the facilitating aspect<br />

<strong>of</strong> strong stakeholder relations. On one h<strong>and</strong>, our definition goes beyond inter-firm<br />

relations, to which Dunning explicitly limits his conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> relational assets,<br />

stating that “unlike most other assets R[elational]-assets are only <strong>of</strong> value when<br />

combined with those <strong>of</strong> other firms” (ibid.: 574). On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the pathdependent<br />

enabling assets accumulate within the firm, in dependence on the<br />

stakeholder goodwill <strong>and</strong> trust that it created over time, with the main purpose to build<br />

a source <strong>of</strong> support <strong>and</strong> relief for times <strong>of</strong> need - be it crisis or change.<br />

6.2.5 Utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based firms - a new perspective<br />

In the early phase <strong>of</strong> defining our research topic we approached the emerging research<br />

questions with a rather narrow focus on the airport industry. As the issues <strong>and</strong> related<br />

questions became more pointed, though, we identified a number <strong>of</strong> industry<br />

characteristics which were applicable also to other - seemingly unrelated - industries.<br />

<strong>Location</strong>-fixity, obviously, was the first common characteristic which we identified,<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ing out most prominently. But we soon discovered other linking elements, which<br />

171 Understood as direct <strong>and</strong> indirect benefits for the stakeholders from the firm's activities, such as the<br />

resulting value share that remains in the region, job opportunities, infrastructure improvements, CSR<br />

projects, etc., such as to comply with stakeholders expectations to the firm.


Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

led us to define a singular type <strong>of</strong> firms, which we termed utilities <strong>and</strong> concessionbased<br />

firms (UCF, see also section 3.4.2). Through the specification <strong>of</strong> UCFs <strong>and</strong> their<br />

characteristics, we add a new perspective to analyse an industry group beyond<br />

conventional utilities, including providers <strong>of</strong> large-scale infrastructures, such as<br />

transportation infrastructure, or quarrying <strong>and</strong> mining, as well as other extractive<br />

industries, or. We therefore <strong>of</strong>fer an alternative perspective to research firms with<br />

subadditive cost <strong>of</strong> production functions, which might lead to additional research <strong>and</strong><br />

useful practical <strong>and</strong> theoretical insights on related phenomena.<br />

6.3 Contributions to practice<br />

As for the practical implications <strong>of</strong> our dissertation, we provide insights mainly - but<br />

not exclusively - to representatives <strong>of</strong> utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based firms. <strong>The</strong><br />

findings may also apply to some extent to firms, which combine a number <strong>of</strong> the<br />

characteristics <strong>of</strong> UCF - most notably location-fixity. With our contributions, we<br />

particularly address site managers; managers <strong>of</strong> corporate social responsibility;<br />

environment, public affairs <strong>and</strong> political lobbying departments; business development;<br />

<strong>and</strong> - specifically in multi-site firms - corporate management <strong>and</strong> those staff functions,<br />

which are concerned with inter-unit collaboration <strong>and</strong> best practice exchange. Table<br />

6-2 provides an overview on the relevance <strong>of</strong> the identified capabilities for local<br />

embedding for the managerial functions, as mentioned above.<br />

339


340<br />

� high relevance<br />

~ medium relevance<br />

Relevance for managerial functions�<br />

Embedding capabilities �<br />

Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

Structural (economic) Relational (social)<br />

Value-share remaining<br />

in region<br />

Mutual lock-in with<br />

stakeholders<br />

Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> selfmonitoring<br />

& governance<br />

<strong>Local</strong> stakeholder<br />

relations<br />

Reputation &<br />

trust-building<br />

Site manager � � � � � �<br />

Corporate social responsibility � � � � �<br />

Environment ~ � ~ �<br />

Public affairs; political lobbying � � ~ � � �<br />

Business development � � � � �<br />

Corporate management & staff functions � � � � ~<br />

Table 6-2: Relevance <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities for managerial functions<br />

Cultural &<br />

institutional adaptation<br />

6.3.1 Long-term view <strong>of</strong> relationship building with stakeholders<br />

<strong>The</strong> explicit linking <strong>of</strong> firms' embedding (capabilities) with value creation in the long<br />

term might change managers' perception <strong>of</strong> firm relations with the local environment.<br />

More precisely, it might induce them to adopt a longer-term view <strong>of</strong> firm-stakeholder<br />

relations <strong>and</strong> the related efforts to relationship building. By identifying the dimensions<br />

for value creation in relation to effective organisational embedding, the indirect effects<br />

<strong>of</strong> such embedding become apparent, as do the hidden costs <strong>of</strong> a weak organisational<br />

legitimacy in the firm's local environment. <strong>The</strong> management thus is able to more<br />

consciously address the need for economic <strong>and</strong> social embedding <strong>and</strong> to orchestrate<br />

activities to this effect. As a result, also the perception <strong>of</strong> costs for these activities - in<br />

particular for the economic embedding - might change, due to a clearer underst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

<strong>of</strong> the benefits <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> the indirect costs <strong>of</strong> weak embedding.<br />

As illustrated schematically in Figure 5-15 we underst<strong>and</strong> the importance <strong>of</strong> enabling<br />

assets by means <strong>of</strong> organisational embedding to vary throughout the asset's life time,<br />

which implies varying intensities <strong>of</strong> embedding activities over the course <strong>of</strong> time.<br />

Importantly, however, these efforts never cease, even in phases <strong>of</strong> smooth operation<br />

<strong>and</strong> when there are no immediate plans for infrastructure or business development.


Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

intensity <strong>of</strong> embedding activities<br />

evaluation<br />

<strong>of</strong> location<br />

firm site<br />

approval<br />

bidding &<br />

negotiation<br />

construction &<br />

start-up preparation<br />

government<br />

concession<br />

approval<br />

start <strong>of</strong><br />

operation<br />

negotiation<br />

for extension<br />

adjustment<br />

to operational<br />

scale or scope<br />

negotiation<br />

for concession<br />

renewal<br />

� � � � �<br />

Figure 6-2: Intensity <strong>of</strong> embedding activities over asset life-time / duration <strong>of</strong> concession<br />

341<br />

t<br />

end <strong>of</strong><br />

concession<br />

In particular managers within the fields <strong>of</strong> corporate social responsibility, public<br />

affairs, <strong>and</strong> to some extent environmental sections may strengthen their argumentation<br />

for an increased focus on their activities, which <strong>of</strong>ten are considered by firms rather as<br />

cost factors than as strategically important value contributors.<br />

6.3.2 Underst<strong>and</strong>ing location-fixity's impacts <strong>and</strong> mitigation possibilities<br />

By more explicitly underst<strong>and</strong>ing the elements <strong>and</strong> impacts <strong>of</strong> location-fixity, the<br />

managers <strong>of</strong> individual sites are better able to address their firm's exposure <strong>and</strong> to<br />

devise according strategies. With our framework <strong>and</strong> the identification <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

<strong>and</strong> social embedding capabilities we therefore contribute to a more contextual<br />

perspective <strong>of</strong> site managers on the firm's environment.<br />

Importantly, a better underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the significance <strong>of</strong> public stakeholders with<br />

regard to the firm's local dependence, <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> the different roles <strong>of</strong> the state, might<br />

induce firms to differently approach the public decision <strong>and</strong> opinion makers. Through<br />

our insights, thus, the managers <strong>of</strong> individual sites may adapt their negotiation<br />

strategies pertaining to the local administration <strong>and</strong> the regulator. <strong>The</strong>se findings are <strong>of</strong><br />

particular importance in pre-project negotiation phases (i.e. before committing to a<br />

site), in expansion <strong>and</strong> business development projects, but also in re-negotiation<br />

phases for concession renewals. In respect <strong>of</strong> any local ownership-dependence due to<br />

public shareholders, managers may better address issues <strong>of</strong> interest alignment <strong>and</strong><br />

governance in order to avoid potential conflicts which might restrict them in their<br />

options for business development.


342<br />

Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

Furthermore, for corporate business developers who are active in diverse cultural <strong>and</strong><br />

institutional contexts, these insights add to the focus on governance mechanisms <strong>and</strong><br />

mutual lock-in. While these factors are relevant to any internationally exp<strong>and</strong>ing firm,<br />

our contribution is to stress the particular consequences for UCF. Due to their sunk<br />

cost investments, the contractual obligations from their concession agreement with the<br />

state, the long time horizon <strong>and</strong> the high public interest in the firm's activities (with a<br />

risk <strong>of</strong> renegotiations), the value at risk involved in these investments is considerably<br />

higher than in more spatially mobile ventures, thus making special precautions<br />

necessary.<br />

6.3.3 Alternative approach to business development<br />

Our research revealed benefits <strong>of</strong> organisational embedding for the business<br />

development opportunities <strong>of</strong> a firm in terms <strong>of</strong> facilitated processes, fewer regulatory<br />

stumble blocks <strong>and</strong> lesser administrative discretion, <strong>and</strong> through a wider range <strong>of</strong><br />

options for such development. As a result to these findings, business developers might<br />

adapt their approach to the planning <strong>and</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong> major projects which have<br />

an impact on the firm's local stakeholders. As we have shown in our research, firms<br />

should involve a broad range <strong>of</strong> stakeholders <strong>and</strong> opinion makers from early stages in<br />

a project, in order to build trust <strong>and</strong> underst<strong>and</strong> their expectations <strong>and</strong> claims. <strong>The</strong><br />

related creative solution-finding processes might involve some costs, but also allow<br />

the firm to tap significant savings potentials with regard to the overall project costs.<br />

Business developers therefore should build <strong>and</strong> accumulate enabling assets with the<br />

firm's key stakeholders on a continuous basis, in order to draw on them when needed<br />

in a concrete project. Our contribution is to provide some guidance with regard to the<br />

dimensions <strong>of</strong> building enabling assets, <strong>and</strong> the related operationalisation <strong>of</strong> these<br />

dimensions.<br />

In addition, our insights help corporate strategists <strong>and</strong> developers in UCFs to support<br />

their local sites in a more focused way. By underst<strong>and</strong>ing the local exposure <strong>of</strong> their<br />

individual sites <strong>and</strong> the need for according embedding capabilities, they may adapt the<br />

job pr<strong>of</strong>iles for the local site management <strong>and</strong> pay higher attention to local managers'<br />

skills in this regard.<br />

6.3.4 Affirmation <strong>of</strong> value creation opportunities in UCF multi-site operations<br />

Pertaining to UCFs' multi-site operations, our practical contribution lies in the<br />

principal affirmation <strong>of</strong> possibilities for value-creation by managing multiple locationfixed<br />

sites. Since existing research has not shed light on the particular conditions <strong>of</strong>


Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

location-fixed firms <strong>and</strong> how these conditions influence multi-site operations,<br />

corporate centres thus obtain new insights in respect <strong>of</strong> value-adding fields <strong>and</strong><br />

activities across sites. We deem these findings crucial in respect <strong>of</strong> firms' strategic<br />

decisions on expansion paths <strong>and</strong> the related options for internationalisation. In case <strong>of</strong><br />

expansion by acquisition, it also helps the UCF to focus its post-acquisition resources<br />

with regard to value creation <strong>and</strong> support <strong>of</strong> the local unit's leadership.<br />

6.3.5 Identification <strong>of</strong> new peer group for exchange<br />

Due to our findings in respect <strong>of</strong> the commonalities among utilities <strong>and</strong> concessionbound<br />

firms, whose group subsumes seemingly distant industries, we allow UCFs to<br />

identify new peers with regard to exchange <strong>of</strong> experience. Thus, firms are able to<br />

exchange their best practices between hitherto considered unrelated industries for<br />

better ways to cope with location-fixity <strong>and</strong> local exposure, <strong>and</strong> to learn from noncompetitors.<br />

6.4 Limitations <strong>of</strong> the dissertation<br />

Through our research we have aimed at contributing to theory by generating new<br />

insights <strong>of</strong> adequate validity <strong>and</strong> generalisability. However, due to a number <strong>of</strong> factors,<br />

which we will detail subsequently, the results underlie certain limitations.<br />

6.5 Methodological <strong>and</strong> empirical limitations<br />

As outlined in sub-chapter 3.2, we have followed grounded theory methodology<br />

throughout our empirical research, using an embedded multiple case design in order to<br />

assess our research questions. While suitable to the nature <strong>of</strong> our research topic, we<br />

would like to call attention to a number <strong>of</strong> methodological limitations which apply to<br />

purely qualitative approaches, as we will more closely specify below.<br />

(1) Generalisability. First <strong>and</strong> foremost, we recognise that there are some bounds to<br />

the generalisability <strong>of</strong> our findings. We have ensured methodological coherence<br />

(Morse, Barrett, Mayan, Olson, & Spiers, 2002) by choosing a qualitative research<br />

approach in line with the theory-building character <strong>of</strong> our research topic. Accordingly,<br />

we have addressed the subject <strong>of</strong> validity by employing an embedded multiple case<br />

design with case study objects from three different industries. We further increased<br />

validity by performing a cross-case comparison, in order to identify inter-industry<br />

patterns <strong>and</strong> commonalities (Eisenhardt, 1989). However, the validity <strong>of</strong> our research<br />

could have been further strengthened by testing additional cases for the replication <strong>of</strong><br />

343


344<br />

Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

our results. Despite the unquestionable advantages <strong>of</strong> a larger number <strong>of</strong> in-depth case<br />

studies, we have decided against this expansion in scope in the interest <strong>of</strong> remaining<br />

focused, <strong>and</strong> in order to avoid a disproportionate increase in the research's complexity.<br />

Thus, <strong>and</strong> in spite <strong>of</strong> the measures taken, any application <strong>of</strong> our theoretical findings<br />

presented in chapter four <strong>and</strong> the related propositions, beyond the specific context <strong>of</strong><br />

the three case objects, requires adequate caution.<br />

Moreover, the applicability <strong>of</strong> our research's findings is explicitly limited to utilities<br />

<strong>and</strong> concession-bound firms. While some findings may have validity beyond this<br />

specified type <strong>of</strong> firms, a wider generalisation would have to be further tested.<br />

(2) Familiarity with the case object. According to Morse (1994), a researcher ideally<br />

needs to face her research object as a 'stranger', before starting to build adequate trust<br />

<strong>and</strong> establish the atmosphere to obtain rich information. This condition has not been<br />

fully complied with in the case <strong>of</strong> our research, as the author works in the business<br />

development department <strong>of</strong> Flughafen Zürich AG, one <strong>of</strong> the three case study objects.<br />

While the pr<strong>of</strong>essional involvement has been particularly valuable in the initial<br />

development <strong>of</strong> the research questions, <strong>and</strong> with regard to deeper investigations<br />

throughout the performed interviews to obtain precise <strong>and</strong> rich information, it entailed<br />

the danger <strong>of</strong> bias during our interviewing phase. However, this risk was mitigated by<br />

the circumstance that all interviews with representatives from Zurich Airport have<br />

been conducted during a period, when the author was on leave for her research project.<br />

Thus, at the time we had no pr<strong>of</strong>essional relations with, or obligations towards the<br />

interviewees, which could have deflected our focus <strong>and</strong> attention. Furthermore,<br />

through our cross-case comparison we were able to ensure some general validation <strong>of</strong><br />

the findings from the airport case.<br />

(3) Triangulation through interviewees' variation in background. In our empirical<br />

research we have interviewed 20 informants from three different firms, with different<br />

hierarchical levels <strong>and</strong> backgrounds. <strong>The</strong>se perspectives were complemented by two<br />

additional interviews from neutral third parties, in order to provide for further<br />

validation <strong>of</strong> the results. Besides, however, our findings could have been further<br />

enriched by additionally collecting information from the stakeholders <strong>of</strong> our case study<br />

objects. In so doing, the 'public' side (as for example local administrations, the<br />

regulator, or public shareholders) <strong>and</strong> the firms' interest groups could have proved<br />

particularly interesting. As a result, such further triangulation might have led to an<br />

even more faceted underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>and</strong> interpretation <strong>of</strong> UCFs' embedding activities <strong>and</strong><br />

to a further strengthening our findings. Notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing these benefits, <strong>and</strong> in


Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

accordance with grounded theory methodology, we have chosen to end the phase <strong>of</strong><br />

interviewing after having reached saturation in our information collection, also with<br />

hindsight to remaining within the defined scope <strong>of</strong> the dissertation.<br />

6.6 <strong>The</strong>oretical limitations<br />

Owing to the choice <strong>of</strong> our research topic, the definition <strong>of</strong> scope, <strong>and</strong> the selection <strong>of</strong><br />

research methodology, we would like to point to a number <strong>of</strong> theoretical limitations<br />

pertaining to our research results.<br />

(1) Multi-faceted research topic. By selecting a multi-faceted research topic for this<br />

dissertation, which entails the use <strong>of</strong> multiple research lenses <strong>and</strong> difficult to<br />

operationalise qualitative constructs, a number <strong>of</strong> theoretical limitations are implied.<br />

While these adequately reflect the topic's complex nature <strong>and</strong> thus are partly<br />

determined by the overall research objective (M. Miles & Huberman, 1994), they<br />

render the development <strong>of</strong> a coherent theory more difficult. Yet, real world phenomena<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten are too complex to do justice to them through simple cause-<strong>and</strong>-effect relations,<br />

requiring also consideration <strong>of</strong> the shades <strong>of</strong> grey in between pure black or white.<br />

Furthermore, in consequence <strong>of</strong> the breadth <strong>of</strong> our approach, the degree <strong>of</strong> theoretical<br />

immersion in the individual research streams remained limited. In other words, the<br />

wide spectre <strong>of</strong> theoretical fields <strong>and</strong> notions which we integrated in our research<br />

framework had a constraining effect on the level <strong>of</strong> detail, with which we ideally<br />

would have liked to reflect on the individual constructs <strong>and</strong> theories. <strong>The</strong>se constraints<br />

particularly apply to the socially more complex notions <strong>of</strong> embeddedness, legitimacy,<br />

<strong>and</strong> trust.<br />

(2) Operationalisation <strong>of</strong> complex qualitative constructs. Due to the nature <strong>of</strong> some<br />

constructs, as well as their partial interleaving with other employed constructs, a<br />

distinct delimitation among them <strong>and</strong> an unambiguous operationalisation regrettably<br />

was unattainable. Endeavours to that end were further impeded by limitations to the<br />

available resources <strong>and</strong> the defined scope <strong>of</strong> our dissertation. Again - <strong>and</strong> also related<br />

to the first limitation - this flaw concerns the elements which pertain to the construct <strong>of</strong><br />

relational embedding capabilities, such as trust <strong>and</strong> reputation, due to their causal<br />

ambiguity, social complexity, <strong>and</strong> their conceptual overlap. Moreover, this observation<br />

also relates to the identified dimensions <strong>of</strong> value creation, which are not distinctly<br />

delineable in all aspects, <strong>and</strong> our conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> value, with which we attempted<br />

to integrate multiple perspectives <strong>and</strong> conceptions.<br />

345


346<br />

Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

(3) Emphasis on single-site view. In the course <strong>of</strong> refining our research questions <strong>and</strong><br />

familiarisation with the various aspects <strong>of</strong> our research topic, we shifted our focus<br />

from an initial intention to analyse location-fixity in multi-site settings to a deeper<br />

discussion <strong>of</strong> a single location-bound site. As outlined before, this shift became<br />

necessary due to the absence <strong>of</strong> thorough theoretical conceptualisations <strong>of</strong> locationfixity<br />

in existing research. As a consequence, we decided to split our research in two<br />

distinct parts, with the multi-site perspective building on the insights from the research<br />

on single sites. Due to this extension <strong>of</strong> scope <strong>and</strong> focus on underst<strong>and</strong>ing individual<br />

sites, we consequently delimited the second part, merely touching upon the<br />

implications <strong>of</strong> value-driven resource management across location-fixed sites.<br />

<strong>The</strong>refore, as we could establish the conceptual basis for local exposure for single<br />

sites, we commend the analysis <strong>of</strong> location-fixity's multi-site implications to further<br />

research.<br />

(4) Rivalling explanations <strong>of</strong> competition's influence on institutional exposure.<br />

Pertaining to the moderating relationship between the firm's competitive environment<br />

<strong>and</strong> its institutional exposure we were not able, within the scope <strong>of</strong> our research, to<br />

obtain a conclusive answer as to the direction <strong>of</strong> the effects. While the results from our<br />

interviews strongly pointed to an influence <strong>of</strong> the competitive environment, the<br />

interviewees' deliberations were ambiguous. We therefore decided to integrate this<br />

moderating construct in our research framework, while leaving open which <strong>of</strong> the<br />

rivalling explanations prevails.<br />

(5) Unidirectional effects <strong>of</strong> institutional exposure. Due to the scope <strong>of</strong> our research<br />

topic <strong>and</strong> the logic <strong>of</strong> our research framework, we merely discussed the firm's<br />

institutional exposure towards its stakeholders <strong>and</strong> excluded a closer reflection on<br />

issues <strong>of</strong> bilateral exposure 172 . Further research with an emphasis on these relations<br />

between the location-fixed firm <strong>and</strong> its stakeholders could bring light to this question.<br />

6.7 Directions for future research<br />

On the basis <strong>of</strong> the identified limitations we would like to commend a number <strong>of</strong><br />

possible themes <strong>and</strong> directions to future research. <strong>The</strong>refore we would like to suggest<br />

the following issues for further analysis <strong>and</strong> inspection.<br />

172 Related aspects, such as reciprocity in human behaviour <strong>and</strong> power imbalances in stakeholder-firm<br />

relations, have been superficially touched upon in the development <strong>of</strong> our framework, albeit without<br />

commensurate elaboration.


Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

6.7.1 Methodological <strong>and</strong> empirical directions<br />

Our research framework has been developed on the basis <strong>of</strong> an embedded multiple<br />

case study, including insights from three unrelated industries. With reference to the<br />

described limitations <strong>of</strong> our approach, particularly pertaining to our findings'<br />

generalisability, we therefore recommend to replicate the cases within other, so far not<br />

empirically considered industries within the group <strong>of</strong> UCI. <strong>The</strong> resulting findings<br />

would not only contribute to further external validation <strong>of</strong> our work, but also lead to<br />

new insights, thus adding empirical evidence to the broader context <strong>of</strong> our research<br />

topic. Above all, further insights could be gained in respect <strong>of</strong> the effects <strong>of</strong> local<br />

exposure on value creation opportunities, as well as the significance <strong>of</strong> the identified<br />

moderators - possibly also suggesting additional moderating factors. Moreover, this<br />

opportunity could also be used to validate <strong>and</strong> extend the insights on the multi-site<br />

resource management <strong>of</strong> UCFs.<br />

In addition to case replication, we also recommend to complement the case studies<br />

with some quantitative methodological elements, including the collection <strong>of</strong> data on a<br />

wider scale by means <strong>of</strong> questionnaires. This additional dimension for triangulation<br />

would strengthen the internal validity <strong>of</strong> the present results. To this effect we suggest<br />

to choose one or more globally present UCFs as research object, with a significant<br />

number <strong>of</strong> geographically widespread sites. Such a setting would possibly also allow<br />

further insights on the effects <strong>of</strong> different institutional <strong>and</strong> cultural environments, as<br />

well as the liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness. Moreover, it would permit a closer analysis <strong>of</strong><br />

value creation in the relations between the corporate parent <strong>and</strong> the individual site,<br />

respectively in inter-site relations <strong>of</strong> location-fixed businesses.<br />

With regard to the moderating factors between location-fixity <strong>and</strong> institutional<br />

exposure, we were not able to single out an unequivocal answer on the effects <strong>of</strong> the<br />

firm's competitive environment: Further assessment <strong>of</strong> this moderator would be<br />

interesting in view <strong>of</strong> the firm's strategic choices for its organisational embedding.<br />

Research results thus would support firms in addressing the expectations <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>s<br />

<strong>of</strong> local stakeholders, in their positioning against local competitors, <strong>and</strong> in their<br />

decisions on fields <strong>of</strong> cooperation with - respectively differentiation from - their<br />

competition.<br />

6.7.2 <strong>The</strong>oretical directions<br />

Further research on UCFs. Having specified the utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-bound firm<br />

within our research, which st<strong>and</strong>s out by a particular set <strong>of</strong> characteristics, we feel that<br />

347


348<br />

Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

additional analysis <strong>of</strong> the thereto related phenomena would be needed, in order to<br />

advance according theoretical <strong>and</strong> managerial insights. Gil <strong>and</strong> Beckman (2009: 8)<br />

rightly observe, that<br />

studies grounded in infrastructure settings <strong>of</strong>fer a rich field for scholarly inquiry<br />

<strong>and</strong> new managerial insights, as well as for testing the validity <strong>of</strong> extant theories<br />

<strong>and</strong> conceptual framing in different settings <strong>and</strong> under different conditions. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

studies can also shed light on best practices suitable to manage the infrastructure<br />

sector.<br />

We therefore suggest three relevant fields for further research on UCFs. First, we have<br />

chosen to analyse the UCF in the context <strong>of</strong> its local environment, with the single site<br />

as unit <strong>of</strong> analysis, respectively the firm's interaction with its local environment.<br />

However, we have only superficially considered the UCF's inter-unit relations,<br />

respectively the relations between the sites <strong>and</strong> the corporate parent. It would be<br />

interesting to return to the second part <strong>of</strong> the research framework once again, in order<br />

to develop a deeper underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the specificities in those relations, <strong>and</strong> how the<br />

corporate parent may support its foreign sites with regard to political <strong>and</strong> regulatory<br />

processes, <strong>and</strong> the general liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness.<br />

Related to the liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness, we have touched on the issue <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

nationalism with regard to internationally active multi-unit UCFs. While the<br />

consequences <strong>and</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> economic nationalism are highly relevant to UCFs - in<br />

particular due to their national strategic relevance, their sovereign m<strong>and</strong>ate, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

quasi-monopolistic industry structures - there is little research on the firm-level effects<br />

within organisation theories. Thus, in order to complement the existing research<br />

mainly attributed to political science, the firm-level analysis <strong>of</strong> the effects <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

nationalism could generate relevant theoretical insights within institutional economics<br />

<strong>and</strong> strategic management research. In addition, the results may have important<br />

practical implications for corporate strategists <strong>and</strong> business developers <strong>of</strong> UCFs.<br />

<strong>The</strong> third recommendation in respect <strong>of</strong> researching UCFs pertains to the subject <strong>of</strong><br />

obsolescing bargain, which we briefly touched upon in chapter four. We believe that a<br />

better underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> governments' incentives to break their long-term commitments<br />

would certainly benefit UCFs in managing their exposure to the public stakeholders.<br />

We therefore suggest an empirical study <strong>of</strong> the frequency, as well as the consequences<br />

<strong>of</strong> obsolescing bargain situations for UCFs in their relations with the state.<br />

Considering that the concept <strong>of</strong> PPP has increased in popularity during the past<br />

decade, <strong>and</strong> that many countries are only in the beginning <strong>of</strong> (partly) privatising their


Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

state-owned firms, the relevance <strong>of</strong> such research becomes evident. <strong>The</strong> findings<br />

would contribute to the identification <strong>of</strong> suitable contracting <strong>and</strong> governance<br />

structures, <strong>and</strong> other effective safeguards. Thus, underst<strong>and</strong>ing the triggers <strong>of</strong><br />

obsolescing bargain <strong>and</strong> deriving effective incentive <strong>and</strong> protection mechanisms<br />

therefore would not only benefit institutional <strong>and</strong> strategic research, but also improve<br />

managerial means to protect the firm's interests.<br />

Moderators to the relation between location-fixity <strong>and</strong> institutional exposure. As<br />

mentioned before, the empirical evidence on the moderators between location-fixity<br />

<strong>and</strong> institutional exposure is either contradictory, as is the case for the firm's<br />

competitive environment, or superficial in the case <strong>of</strong> the firm's local economic<br />

relevance. On one h<strong>and</strong>, the clarification <strong>of</strong> the rivalling explanations on the effect <strong>of</strong><br />

competition would generate insights on UCFs' strategic choices to lower their<br />

exposure in a competitive environment. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, a thorough analysis <strong>of</strong><br />

UCFs' relevance within the local economy <strong>and</strong> how its role affects its institutional<br />

exposure would benefit an underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the related processes in local politics <strong>and</strong><br />

public administration.<br />

6.8 Final conclusions<br />

By means <strong>of</strong> this dissertation we have aimed to contribute to a better underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong><br />

the particular circumstances <strong>of</strong> utilities <strong>and</strong> concession-based firms - a category <strong>of</strong><br />

firms defined for the purpose - <strong>and</strong> their opportunities for value creation. Through the<br />

resulting research framework we have underlined a holistic view <strong>of</strong> the UCF,<br />

combining institutional <strong>and</strong> strategic perspectives <strong>and</strong> taking adequate account <strong>of</strong> the<br />

UCF's context, respectively its local environment. It was our aspiration to not only<br />

contribute to a new lens on infrastructure-heavy industries from a theoretical side, but<br />

to additionally help practitioners in focusing their limited resources for local<br />

embedding in value-creating ways, <strong>and</strong> to better underst<strong>and</strong> the corporate parent's<br />

value contribution in multi-site settings.<br />

Our key contributions therefore are threefold: Firstly, by analysing the characteristics<br />

<strong>and</strong> workings <strong>of</strong> location-fixity, we have drawn attention to the relevance <strong>of</strong> the spatial<br />

dimension <strong>and</strong> immobility for the firm's value creation opportunities. From a<br />

theoretical perspective, we thus have conceptualised spatial fixity as an additional<br />

dimension to strategic management's concept <strong>of</strong> asset specificity. From a practitioner's<br />

point <strong>of</strong> view, our insights contribute to an increased awareness on the influences <strong>of</strong><br />

local dependence with regard to options for future development, <strong>and</strong> to a better<br />

349


350<br />

Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the firm's local exposure towards its individual stakeholders.<br />

<strong>The</strong>reby, the insights on public stakeholders are <strong>of</strong> particular relevance to the firm's<br />

value creation.<br />

Secondly, the identification <strong>of</strong> two key dimensions <strong>of</strong> embedding capabilities, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

respective sub-categories has relevance to theory <strong>and</strong> practice. In distinguishing<br />

between economic <strong>and</strong> social embedding capabilities, we bridge the institutional focus<br />

on relational factors in the firm's context, <strong>and</strong> the more instrumental view <strong>of</strong> strategic<br />

management <strong>and</strong> transaction-cost economics. We thus add to the notion, that socially<br />

responsible firm behaviour incurs costs in the short term, but has a return on<br />

investment in the medium <strong>and</strong> long term. <strong>The</strong> conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> embedding<br />

capabilities contributes to managerial decision-making with regard to the firm's<br />

strategic paths, <strong>and</strong> with regard to the supporting embedding activities that are needed<br />

to facilitate strategy implementation. Most importantly, by underst<strong>and</strong>ing the relevant<br />

dimensions <strong>of</strong> embedding, managers gain insights on the possibilities to mitigate the<br />

negative effects <strong>of</strong> local exposure, respectively to leverage the positive ones.<br />

<strong>The</strong> third key contribution pertains to the resource management <strong>of</strong> multi-site UCFs.<br />

Since the global expansion <strong>of</strong> many UCFs raised questions <strong>of</strong> business logic <strong>and</strong> value<br />

contribution over the past years, our insights support the view that even for locationfixed<br />

businesses there are distinct possibilities for value creation in multi-site<br />

management. As a consequence, our insights might influence corporate strategists'<br />

recommendations with regard to internationalisation. In addition, through our research<br />

we have identified areas, where corporate parents should <strong>of</strong>fer support <strong>and</strong> experience<br />

to their location-bound sites, respectively areas which we recommend to be h<strong>and</strong>led<br />

solely through the local management. Finally, the specification <strong>of</strong> embedding<br />

capabilities <strong>and</strong> emphasis <strong>of</strong> their importance might also influence the firm's recruiting<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>ile for local site managers, thus contributing to an aligned underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the<br />

firm's behavioural values <strong>and</strong> approach to local relationship-building.<br />

Our findings' utility <strong>and</strong> relevance are enhanced by the fact that we are in the middle<br />

<strong>of</strong> a global wave <strong>of</strong> privatisation, which started a quarter <strong>of</strong> a century ago in the UK<br />

<strong>and</strong> continues to date in Europe, throughout Asia, <strong>and</strong> to some extent in the United<br />

States. <strong>The</strong> involvement <strong>of</strong> private parties in formerly state-controlled activities is<br />

additionally fostered by a growing need for new infrastructure, <strong>and</strong> the modernisation<br />

<strong>of</strong> existing infrastructure in fast developing countries 173 , such as China or India.<br />

173 A recent report from the OECD estimates the spending required to update infrastructure in<br />

developed countries <strong>and</strong> to develop appropriate infrastructure in emerging economies at USD 53


Discussion <strong>of</strong> Results <strong>and</strong> Conclusions<br />

However, privatisation processes are not always smooth, <strong>and</strong> sometimes significantly<br />

hurt the private investors, as the recent case <strong>of</strong> Ferrovial's engagement in British<br />

Airport Authorities (BAA) illustrates, where the Competition Commission<br />

recommended the breaking up <strong>of</strong> BAA's monopoly on London's airports shortly after<br />

the change <strong>of</strong> ownership. Underst<strong>and</strong>ing the characteristics <strong>of</strong> UCFs <strong>and</strong> the resulting<br />

exposure towards the local environment therefore may have very practical relevance.<br />

We have shed light in particular on the firm's institutional exposure towards its public<br />

stakeholders, crucial in private investor engagements, the successful setting up <strong>of</strong><br />

PPP's, <strong>and</strong> in the public <strong>and</strong> private parties' alignment <strong>of</strong> interests. By acknowledging<br />

the importance <strong>of</strong> elements <strong>of</strong> governance, adequate local adaptation to overcome<br />

liabilities <strong>of</strong> foreignness, <strong>and</strong> relational aspects in the management <strong>of</strong> their public<br />

stakeholders, firms are not only better prepared for the strategic management <strong>of</strong> their<br />

cognitive-cultural <strong>and</strong> political risks, thus protecting their undertakings, but also to<br />

leverage their resources in value creating ways.<br />

We would like to conclude with an observation by Gil <strong>and</strong> Beckman (2009: 7f), who<br />

contend that “surprisingly, … infrastructure has still received limited attention from<br />

management studies even if research on the interplay among the regulation, politics,<br />

<strong>and</strong> economics <strong>of</strong> infrastructure has a long empirical <strong>and</strong> analytical tradition”. With<br />

the present dissertation we have taken a step towards filling this gap, providing<br />

managers <strong>of</strong> UCFs with valuable insights on their business specifics, <strong>and</strong> hoping to<br />

bring impetus also for future research to follow.<br />

trillion between 2007 <strong>and</strong> 2030; advising developed nations to invest at least 2.5% <strong>of</strong> their GDP in<br />

infrastructure (OECD, 2007).<br />

351


352<br />

Appendices<br />

Appendix 1: Overview on case study objects<br />

Appendix 2: <strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> interview partners<br />

Appendix 3: Interview guideline, example<br />

Appendices


Appendices<br />

Appendix 1: Overview on case study objects<br />

Case: Axpo Group<br />

Industry Energy<br />

Organisation<br />

Form<br />

Founded in 2001<br />

Financial holding; the group comprises Axpo AG, Centralschweizerische Kraftwerke AG (CKW) <strong>and</strong><br />

Elektrizitäts-Gesellschaft Laufenburg AG (EGL), as well as Axpo Informatik AG.<br />

Revenue 2008/2009: CHF 7'550m<br />

Employees 2008/2009: 4'100 FTE<br />

Axpo Holding AG<br />

Central-<br />

Elektrizitäts-<br />

Axpo AG schweizerische<br />

Gesellschaft Axpo Informatik AG<br />

Kraftwerke AG Laufenburg AG<br />

Description Axpo trades with electricity, gas <strong>and</strong> energy-related financial products in all <strong>of</strong> Europe <strong>and</strong> supplies 3<br />

million people <strong>and</strong> thous<strong>and</strong>s <strong>of</strong> companies in Switzerl<strong>and</strong> with what they need for day-to-day living <strong>and</strong> to<br />

keep the economy going: energy.<br />

Corporate<br />

Philosophy<br />

<strong>The</strong> cornerstones <strong>of</strong> Axpo’s strategy:<br />

- to exp<strong>and</strong> its position as an energy supply company in Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

- to ensure reliability <strong>of</strong> supply with its own production capacities<br />

- to exp<strong>and</strong> its trading activities in order to improve links to other countries <strong>and</strong> to make the most <strong>of</strong><br />

opportunities on the European market<br />

We have common values.<br />

We communicate openly, actively <strong>and</strong> honestly. We say what we do <strong>and</strong> do what we say. Our conduct is<br />

characterised by integrity, personal responsibility, trust, tolerance <strong>and</strong> respect.<br />

We create added value.<br />

We want our customers <strong>and</strong> partners to benefit from working with us. This is why we <strong>of</strong>fer innovative<br />

products <strong>and</strong> services.<br />

We shape our future.<br />

We want to be constantly pr<strong>of</strong>itable <strong>and</strong> create added value for our shareholders. In this way we can ensure<br />

that we have the freedom to act <strong>and</strong> that we will remain competitive.<br />

We are proud <strong>of</strong> our employees.<br />

We employ qualified, motivated <strong>and</strong> performance-driven employees with excellent social <strong>and</strong> specialist<br />

skills. We <strong>of</strong>fer an attractive working environment that fosters above-average performance. We expect our<br />

managerial staff to set an example to all employees.<br />

We act prudently.<br />

Our conduct towards people <strong>and</strong> the environment is shaped by responsibility <strong>and</strong> security awareness.<br />

We are pacesetters.<br />

We identify <strong>and</strong> exploit new opportunities at an early stage.<br />

353


354<br />

Financial<br />

interests<br />

Joint ventures <strong>and</strong> other equity-consolidated companies - 74; there<strong>of</strong> abroad - 15<br />

Fully consolidated companies - 18<br />

Ownership Limited company, wholly owned by the cantons <strong>of</strong> North-Eastern Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

Axpo's Hydropower Assets<br />

Canton <strong>of</strong> Zürich 18%<br />

Elektrizitätswerke des Kantons Zürich 18%<br />

Canton <strong>of</strong> Aargau 14%<br />

AEW ENERGIE AG 14%<br />

St. Gallisch-Appenzellische Kraftwerke AG 13%<br />

Elektrizitätswerk des Kantons Thurgau AG 12%<br />

Canton <strong>of</strong> Schaffhausen 8%<br />

Canton <strong>of</strong> Glarus 2%<br />

Canton <strong>of</strong> Zug 1%<br />

Owned <strong>and</strong> operated Operated (majority stake) Minority stake<br />

1. Hydraulisches Kraftwerk Beznau<br />

2. Kraftwerk Fätschbach<br />

3. Kraftwerk am Löntsch<br />

4. Kraftwerk Rüchlig<br />

5. Kraftwerk Wildegg-Brugg<br />

6. Kraftwerk Rathausen (CKW)<br />

7. Kraftwerk Emmenweid (CKW)<br />

8. Kraftwerk Sarneraa (CKW)<br />

1. Aarewerke AG<br />

2. Albula-L<strong>and</strong>wasser Kraftwerke AG<br />

3. Argessa AG<br />

4. Kraftwerk Augst AG<br />

5. Calancasca AG<br />

6. KW Eglisau-Glattfelden AG<br />

7. Elettricità Industriale SA<br />

8. Kraftwerke Frisal AG<br />

9. Kraftwerke Ilanz AG<br />

10. Kraftwerke Linth-Limmern AG<br />

11. Kraftwerke Mattmark AG<br />

12. Kraftwerke Mauvoisin AG<br />

13. Misoxer Kraftwerke AG<br />

14. Rheinkraftwerk Neuhausen AG<br />

15. Axpo Hydro Surselva AG<br />

16. Kraftwerk Reckingen AG<br />

17. Kraftwerke Reichenau AG<br />

18. Elektrizitätswerk Rheinau AG<br />

19. Kraftwerk Rupperswil-Auenstein AG<br />

20. Kraftwerke Sarganserl<strong>and</strong> AG<br />

21. Tecnicama AG<br />

22. Kraftwerke Vorderrhein AG<br />

23. AG Kraftwerk Wägital<br />

24. Calancasca AG (CKW)<br />

25. Engadiner KW AG (CKW)<br />

26. FM Mauvoisin SA (CKW)<br />

27. KW Göschenen AG (CKW)<br />

28. KW Mattmark AG (CKW)<br />

29. KW Wassen AG (CKW)<br />

30. Misoxer KW AG (CKW)<br />

Appendices<br />

1. Blenio Kraftwerke AG<br />

2. Electra-Massa AG<br />

3. Engadiner Kraftwerke AG<br />

4. Gr<strong>and</strong>e Dixence SA<br />

5. Kraftwerke Hinterrhein AG<br />

6. Maggia Kraftwerke AG<br />

7. Kraftwerk Ryburg-<br />

Schwörstadt AG<br />

8. Rheinkraftwerk Säckingen<br />

AG<br />

9. Kraftwerk Schaffhausen AG<br />

10. Kraftwerke Zervreila AG


Appendices<br />

Case: Flughafen Zürich AG<br />

Industry Airport operation & maintenance<br />

Organisation<br />

Form<br />

Public limited company, functional organisation<br />

Operations<br />

Marketing &<br />

Real Estate<br />

Board <strong>of</strong> Directors<br />

CEO<br />

Founded in 2000 as a result <strong>of</strong> the airport operator's privatisation<br />

Revenue 2009: CHF 820m<br />

Employees 2009: 1'549 FTE<br />

Finance Services<br />

Description As a transport hub Zurich Airport connects Switzerl<strong>and</strong> with destinations all over the world. It is also a<br />

shopping, cultural <strong>and</strong> services centre. Through its employees' motivation <strong>and</strong> commitment, as well as their<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>essional know-how <strong>and</strong> hospitality, Zurich airport has been able to continuously strengthen its good<br />

reputation <strong>and</strong> to become one <strong>of</strong> the best-in-class airports worldwide.<br />

Corporate<br />

Philosophy<br />

Other decisive factors for the sustainable development <strong>of</strong> Zurich Airport are the consistent implementation<br />

<strong>of</strong> measures to protect the environment, <strong>and</strong> the active integration <strong>of</strong> business partners, local residents <strong>and</strong> all<br />

relevant authorities into the activities <strong>of</strong> the airport.<br />

It operator, Flughafen Zuerich AG, has been awarded a concession by the Swiss Federation to operate Zurich<br />

Airport until 2051.<br />

Management Principles<br />

- we behave in the way we expect our employees to behave<br />

- we focus on the company’s objectives <strong>and</strong> orient our employees’ goals on them<br />

- we communicate openly, appropriately <strong>and</strong> punctually<br />

- we permit critical questions about existing <strong>and</strong> planned activities<br />

- we create a credible environment <strong>of</strong> mutual trust for employees <strong>and</strong> team members<br />

- we challenge <strong>and</strong> support employees, help them to learn from mistakes, <strong>and</strong> reward good performance<br />

- we clearly communicate expectations (goals, priorities, quality, responsibility)<br />

- we communicate decisions clearly <strong>and</strong> comprehensibly, abide by them <strong>and</strong> put them into action<br />

consistently<br />

- we delegate responsibility wherever possible, but always together with the necessary competencies <strong>and</strong><br />

required information<br />

Mission Statement<br />

We perceive it as our duty to strengthen Switzerl<strong>and</strong> as a business centre, as a country with a rich tradition <strong>of</strong><br />

culture, know-how <strong>and</strong> sport, <strong>and</strong> as an attractive tourist destination, by operating a well-developed <strong>and</strong><br />

efficient gateway to the world.<br />

As a lively <strong>and</strong> inter-cultural commercial centre we provide innovative services <strong>of</strong> national <strong>and</strong> international<br />

appeal in line with the broad-ranging needs <strong>of</strong> our clients.<br />

We make the best possible use <strong>of</strong> our know-how in Switzerl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> abroad by developing <strong>and</strong> implementing<br />

projects aimed at enhancing economic performance <strong>and</strong> efficiency.<br />

We distinguish ourselves from our competitors by consistently implementing positive Swiss values – i.e.<br />

“Swissness”.<br />

355


356<br />

Financial<br />

interests<br />

Appendices<br />

We focus on consumers (passengers <strong>and</strong> visitors to the airport). We take note <strong>of</strong> their expectations, their<br />

behaviour <strong>and</strong> their pr<strong>of</strong>iles, as well as their assessment <strong>of</strong> the quality <strong>of</strong> services at Zurich Airport, <strong>and</strong><br />

incorporate our findings into our decision-making processes. We are always friendly <strong>and</strong> helpful towards our<br />

clients. We set out to ensure that consumers perceive Zurich Airport as open, reliable, safe, convenient <strong>and</strong><br />

welcoming, but also as diverse, innovative, forward-looking, unique <strong>and</strong> trendsetting.<br />

Bangalore International Airport Ltd. (BIAL) 5.0%<br />

A-port S.A. (Brazil) 15.0%<br />

A-port Operaciones S.A. (Chile) 32.6%<br />

Ownership Publicly traded company with two major public shareholders (31.12.2009):<br />

Canton <strong>of</strong> Zurich 33.3%<br />

City <strong>of</strong> Zurich 5.0 %


Appendices<br />

Case: Holcim<br />

Industry Cement <strong>and</strong> Building Materials<br />

Organisation<br />

Form<br />

Founded in 1912<br />

Revenue<br />

Financial holding<br />

Executive<br />

Committee<br />

Regional Line<br />

Responsibility<br />

Functional<br />

Responsibility<br />

2009: CHF 21'132 m<br />

2008: CHF 25'157 m<br />

Employees 2009: 81'500 FTE<br />

Audit Committee<br />

Internal Audit<br />

A<br />

Board <strong>of</strong> Directors Holcim Ltd.<br />

CEO<br />

357<br />

Governance, Nomination &<br />

Compensation Committee<br />

B C …<br />

Region a Region b Region c …<br />

X Y Z …<br />

Description Holcim is one <strong>of</strong> the leading suppliers <strong>of</strong> cement <strong>and</strong> aggregates (crushed stone, s<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> gravel) as well as<br />

ready-mix concrete <strong>and</strong> asphalt, <strong>and</strong> related services.<br />

Corporate<br />

Philosophy<br />

Vision<br />

Our vision is to provide foundations for society’s future.<br />

We have evolved from a single company acquiring interests in local companies around the world into a<br />

leading global group that can meet the challenges <strong>of</strong> an increasingly competitive global marketplace. Our<br />

central strategies <strong>and</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ards empower Group companies, while enabling their autonomy <strong>and</strong> leveraging<br />

their local strengths to the benefit <strong>of</strong> all.<br />

We are trusted partners to the communities in which we live <strong>and</strong> work. We provide enduring value <strong>and</strong><br />

constancy through the jobs we create, our active social involvement in each local community, <strong>and</strong> our<br />

stewardship <strong>of</strong> the environment <strong>and</strong> sustainable resources for future generations. We provide foundations for<br />

people’s growth through our commitment to developing the full potential <strong>of</strong> our employees <strong>and</strong> partners.<br />

Mission Statement<br />

Our mission is to be the world’s most respected <strong>and</strong> attractive company in our industry – creating value for all<br />

our stakeholders.<br />

We are a worldwide supplier <strong>of</strong> cementitious materials <strong>and</strong> related services to the construction markets. We<br />

strive to leverage our shared experience <strong>and</strong> knowledge throughout our global network, actively applying this<br />

excellence to where it has the greatest benefit – in the markets <strong>and</strong> communities in which we operate.<br />

We regard our stakeholders, especially our customers, distributors <strong>and</strong> suppliers within the construction<br />

industry, as partners <strong>and</strong> endeavor to integrate them in our decision-making process – working collaboratively<br />

to develop innovative pr<strong>of</strong>essional solutions


358<br />

Financial<br />

interests<br />

Our goals are to:<br />

- Continually set the highest st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>of</strong> customer satisfaction in our industry<br />

- Secure the strongest competitive position in our markets<br />

- Partner with suppliers to deliver value-for-cost procurement for the Group <strong>and</strong> our customers<br />

- Be recognized as an employer <strong>of</strong> first choice<br />

- Empower our employees <strong>and</strong> integrate them fully into our global network<br />

- Selectively grow our worldwide presence <strong>of</strong> companies<br />

- Demonstrate our commitment to sustainable development<br />

- Be acknowledged as a valued <strong>and</strong> trusted partner in our community<br />

- Be the most recommended stock in our industry<br />

Principal joint ventures / equity-consolidated companies - 57 worldwide (2009)<br />

Ownership Publicly traded company with three major shareholders (31.12.2009):<br />

Thomas Schmidheiny 18.2 %<br />

Capital Group Companies Inc. 5.0 %<br />

Eurocement Holding AG 6.5 %<br />

Free Float (as defined by the SIX Swiss Exchange) 82.0 %<br />

Appendices


Appendices<br />

Appendix 2: <strong>List</strong> <strong>of</strong> interview partners<br />

359


360<br />

Appendix 3: Interview guideline, example<br />

Appendices<br />

Interview mit<br />

Christian Lindner, Leiter Primäranlagen & Bau und<br />

Martin Everts, Leiter Business Development Axpo AG<br />

Einführung<br />

Dieses Interview ist Teil einer Case Study zu Ihrem Unternehmen, welche im Rahmen eines<br />

Dissertationsprojektes an der Universität St. Gallen durchgeführt wird.<br />

Das Forschungsthema beschäftigt sich mit St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit von Unternehmen, ein Umst<strong>and</strong> der<br />

in hohem Masse auch auf die Energiebranche zutrifft. St<strong>and</strong>ortgebunden ist ein Unternehmen dann,<br />

wenn zum einen die eingesetzten Ressourcen st<strong>and</strong>ortgebunden sind, aber auch wenn das<br />

Unternehmen durch die vielfältigen Beziehungen zu seinem Umfeld lokal eingebettet und somit<br />

immobil ist. Beispiele dafür sind die Verbindung mit kritischen Zulieferern oder Kunden vor Ort,<br />

regulatorische und politische Vernetzung, sowie die Einbettung in die lokale Gemeinschaft.<br />

Im Rahmen des Forschungsprojektes soll untersucht werden,<br />

- was St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit ausmacht,<br />

- inwiefern St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit die Zusammenarbeit zwischen mehreren St<strong>and</strong>orten beeinflusst,<br />

und<br />

- unter welchen Bedingungen diese einschränkend wirkt oder vorteilhaft genutzt werden kann.<br />

Aus den Ergebnissen werden H<strong>and</strong>lungsempfehlungen für die Praxis erarbeitet, die helfen sollen,<br />

gezielter mit den Konsequenzen der St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit umzugehen, und deren Eigenschaften im<br />

Hinblick auf Wertgenerierung (value creation) und Realisierung von Synergien zu nutzen.<br />

Mit Hilfe dieses Interviews sollen Erkenntnisse über die Erfahrungen in Ihrem Tätigkeitsbereich<br />

gewonnen werden, um den Sachverhalt und die Wirkungszusammenhänge der St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit<br />

für die Energiebranche transparenter zu machen.


Appendices<br />

TEIL I: Unternehmensstruktur und Ihre Rolle im Unternehmen<br />

Abläufe im Unternehmen werden über die Struktur (Aufbauorganisation), Prozessregelungen<br />

(Ablauforganisation) und Selbstorganisation (informelle Organisation) definiert. In diesem ersten<br />

Interview-Teil stehen die Aufbauorganisation Ihres Unternehmens im Vordergrund, sowie die<br />

Beziehung des Hauptsitzes mit den Tochterunternehmen oder Beteiligungen.<br />

1. Bitte beschreiben Sie kurz die Struktur Ihres Unternehmens (Organigramms, St<strong>and</strong>orte).<br />

2. Welche Funktion und Rolle nehmen Sie im Unternehmen ein (Positionsbezeichnung, evt. mit<br />

Kommentar / Anmerkungen)?<br />

3. Bitte beschreiben Sie grob die Zusammenarbeit zwischen Axpo AG und der Axpo Holding.<br />

Welche Rolle nimmt die Holding ein bezüglich der verschiedenen Beteiligungen?<br />

TEIL II: St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit, Branchenspezifika und Zusammenarbeit zwischen den<br />

St<strong>and</strong>orten<br />

Der Begriff St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit kann aus verschiedenen Perspektiven betrachtet werden. Im<br />

Forschungskontext dieses Projektes wird St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit unter folgenden drei Dimensionen<br />

beleuchtet:<br />

- Ressourcenaspekt: Bindung an kritische Ressourcen, welche an diesem bestimmten St<strong>and</strong>ort<br />

verfügbar sind und nicht oder nur unter hohen Kosten verlegt werden können<br />

- Beziehungs- und Einbettungsaspekt: Bindung an bestimmte Akteure - Unternehmen, Politiker,<br />

Regulator, lokale Gemeinschaft - welche kritisch für das Verfolgen des Unternehmenszwecks sind<br />

- Regulatorischer Aspekt: regulatorisches Regelwerk und strukturelle Faktoren, innert welchen<br />

sich das Unternehmen zu bewegen gelernt hat und unter welchen es sich legitimiert<br />

4. Was bedeutet St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit für Ihr Unternehmen auf den drei erwähnten Dimensionen?<br />

Was charakterisiert sie und woraus ergibt sie sich?<br />

5. Wo sind die markantesten Unterschiede im Vergleich zu einem herkömmlichen<br />

Produktionsbetrieb? Sehen Sie diese Unterschiede als Vorteil, als Nachteil?<br />

6. Inwiefern beeinflusst St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit die Zusammenarbeit zwischen Ihren St<strong>and</strong>orten?<br />

Wirkt sie sich auf Kosten, Umsatzpotentiale oder <strong>and</strong>ere Möglichkeiten zur Wertgenerierung<br />

Ihres Unternehmens aus?<br />

7. Bitte beschreiben Sie einige Beispiele für Zusammenarbeit zwischen Ihrem Unternehmen und<br />

den Beteiligungen, bzw. zwischen den verschiedenen St<strong>and</strong>orten.<br />

- gibt es Unterschiede?<br />

- gute Beispiele?<br />

- schlechte Beispiele?<br />

361


362<br />

Appendices<br />

8. Tauscht Ihr Unternehmen physische oder immaterielle Ressourcen (intangible resources) aus?<br />

Inwiefern spielen Wissen und Fähigkeiten eine Rolle in der Zusammenarbeit zwischen den<br />

St<strong>and</strong>orten?<br />

TEIL III: Ressourcenaspekt der St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit<br />

Ressourcen sollen in diesem Kontext als greifbare Ressourcen (tangibles), aber auch als Kompetenzen<br />

und Fähigkeiten (intangibles) verst<strong>and</strong>en werden. Für das Unternehmen kritische Ressourcen können<br />

definiert werden als "firm-specific assets that are difficult if not impossible to imitate; examples are<br />

trade secrets <strong>and</strong> certain specialized production facilities <strong>and</strong> engineering experience" [Teece, D. J.,<br />

Pisano, G., & Shuen, A. (1997)].<br />

9. Welches sind aus Ihrer Sicht die erfolgskritischen Ressourcen (tangible / intangible) der Axpo<br />

AG?<br />

- in Bezug auf einzelne St<strong>and</strong>orte / Grossprojekte und deren Management<br />

- als Gesamtunternehmen im Management mehrerer St<strong>and</strong>orte<br />

10. Welche Aspekte stehen bei Axpo bezüglich dem Management mehrerer St<strong>and</strong>orte im<br />

Vordergrund? 174 Gibt es Beispiele für die Nutzung von Synergien?<br />

� Bitte um Angabe der Wichtigkeit der einzelnen Aspekte<br />

0 … keine, 1 … gering, 2 … mittel, 3 … hoch, - … keine Angabe<br />

- Operative Synergien:<br />

Leistungsvorteile von Unternehmen aus vorteilhaftem Einsatz ihrer operativen Ressourcen über das<br />

Gesamtgeschäft<br />

__ Economies <strong>of</strong> Scope (Verbundvorteile)<br />

__ Steigerung der Produktivität, Reduktion von Ineffizienzen<br />

__ Austausch von Best Practices<br />

__ Wachstumssynergien (z.B. neue Produkte durch kombinierte Ressourcen)<br />

__ ____________________________________________________<br />

- Marktmacht-Synergien:<br />

Leistungsvorteile von Unternehmen aus vorteilhaftem Einsatz ihrer Verh<strong>and</strong>lungsressourcen über das<br />

Gesamtgeschäft<br />

__ Preisgestaltung<br />

__ Bundling, Bündelung von Leistungen<br />

__ Gegenseitige Absatzbeziehungen<br />

__ Konsolidierungsdruck aus Branchenentwicklung<br />

__ ____________________________________________________<br />

174 Kategorisierung auf Basis von Knoll (2008).


Appendices<br />

- Finanzielle Synergien (Financial Engineering):<br />

Leistungsvorteile von Unternehmen aus vorteilhaftem Einsatz ihrer finanziellen Möglichkeiten über das<br />

Gesamtgeschäft<br />

__ Optimierung der Kapitalstruktur (interner Kapitalmarkt)<br />

__ Reduktion der Gesamtsteuerlast<br />

__ Finanzielle Skalenerträge<br />

(Transaktions-/Emissionskosten von Fremd-/Eigenkapital)<br />

__ Reduktion des Unternehmensrisikos<br />

__ ____________________________________________________<br />

- Corporate Management Synergien<br />

Leistungsvorteile von Unternehmen aus vorteilhaftem Einsatz ihrer Management-Ressourcen über das<br />

Gesamtgeschäft<br />

__ Unternehmerische Fähigkeiten<br />

__ Fähigkeiten im Organisationsdesign<br />

__ Strategische Fähigkeiten<br />

__ ____________________________________________________<br />

TEIL IV: Beziehungs- und Einbettungsaspekt der St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit - Interaktionsebene<br />

Es liegt in der Natur von Unternehmen, dass sie mit ihrem Umfeld in Interaktion sind, um ihre<br />

Funktionalität zu erhalten. Beziehungen bestehen beispielsweise durch den lokalen Arbeitsmarkt,<br />

Lieferantennetzwerke, oder Absatzmärkte. Diese Einbettung in das lokale Umfeld (local<br />

embeddedness) kann auch umschrieben werden als "the way in which organisations or actors become<br />

tied in to the local business <strong>and</strong> institutional environment" [Alderman (2004)]. Der folgende<br />

Gesprächsabschnitt konzentriert sich auf die Umfeld-Beziehungen von Axpo AG, und in welcher<br />

Weise diese erfolgsrelevant sind.<br />

11. Was bedeutet 'local embeddedness' für Ihre Branche, Ihr Unternehmen, das Management der<br />

St<strong>and</strong>orte?<br />

12. Welche Rolle spielen in Ihrer Branche die Stakeholder rund um einen St<strong>and</strong>ort für dessen<br />

Wertschöpfung? Welches sind die relevanten Stakeholder?<br />

13. Wie wichtig ist es in Ihren Projekten, dass ein Teil der Wertschöpfung des Unternehmens vor Ort<br />

bleibt?<br />

14. Bitte beschreiben Sie einige Beispiele für die Zusammenarbeit zwischen einem St<strong>and</strong>ort und den<br />

relevanten Stakeholdern? Gibt es Unterschiede? Gute und weniger erfolgreiche Beispiele?<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit bedingt meistens auch eine Komponente der gegenseitigen Abhängigkeit<br />

zwischen Unternehmen und Region. Die folgenden Fragen sollen ausloten, mit welchen<br />

Möglichkeiten die Region St<strong>and</strong>ortabhängigkeit für Unternehmen attraktiv(er) machen kann.<br />

363


364<br />

Appendices<br />

15. Welche Erfahrungen haben Sie an den verschiedenen St<strong>and</strong>orten in der Zusammenarbeit mit<br />

regionalen Administrationen gemacht? In welchen Rollen sehen sich die lokalen Volksvertreter<br />

hauptsächlich?<br />

16. Hat sich die Zusammenarbeit zwischen (Tochter-)Unternehmen und den Regionen, in denen Sie<br />

St<strong>and</strong>orte haben über die Jahre verändert?<br />

17. Was könnte eine Region aus Ihrer Sicht unternehmen, um die St<strong>and</strong>ortattraktivität für den<br />

jeweiligen St<strong>and</strong>ort zu erhöhen und somit die Vorteile von St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit und<br />

Verankerung zu erhöhen?<br />

18. Inwiefern könnte die Region dazu beitragen, die Risk Bearing Capacity des St<strong>and</strong>orts zu erhöhen<br />

(ein Beispiel wäre die Sicherung der Ressourcen-Verfügbarkeit über Zeit, also z.B. bei einem<br />

Holzkraftwerk die lokale Verfügbarkeit von Holz, oder bei einem Flughafen die Betriebszeiten /<br />

L<strong>and</strong>e- und Startkapazität)?<br />

19. Was wäre Ihre Vision der idealen lokalen Zusammenarbeit? Welche Plattformen / Strukturen<br />

bräuchte es dafür?<br />

TEIL V: Regulatorischer Aspekt - strukturelle Ebene<br />

In den meisten Branchen mit hoher St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit spielt das regulatorische Umfeld eine<br />

bedeutende Rolle. Regulatorische Aspekte sind beispielsweise gesetzliche Verpflichtungen, Auflagen,<br />

Einschränkungen bez. Wettbewerb, Preisgestaltung, Konzessionen und Property Rights, etc.<br />

20. Wie signifikant schätzen Sie die regulatorischen Aspekte für Ihre Branche ein?<br />

21. Ist der regulatorische Rahmen insgesamt eher einengend oder bietet er auch Chancen? Was sind<br />

die negativen Auswirkungen und welches die Vorteile?<br />

22. Stufen Sie Ihr Unternehmen als pro-aktiv oder reaktiv ein, mit Bezug auf regulatorische <strong>The</strong>men?<br />

23. Bitte beschreiben Sie die Rolle des Regulators in der Interaktion mit Ihrem Unternehmen. Wie<br />

nimmt Ihr Unternehmen den Regulator wahr?<br />

24. Welche Beziehung pflegt Ihr Unternehmen zum Regulator? Wie ist der Zugang zum Regulator<br />

organisatorisch geregelt?


Appendices<br />

TEIL VI: Mini-Cases<br />

Auf der Basis der vorangehenden Fragen soll in diesem Gesprächsteil je ein erfolgreiches (z.B. Linth-<br />

Limmern) und ein weniger erfolgreiches Projekt gegenübergestellt werden, wo Axpo AG ihre<br />

Interessen unter Berücksichtigung der lokalen Stakeholder verfolgt.<br />

25. Grosse Infrastruktur-Projekte in Ihrer Branche haben zumeist eine hohe Öffentlichkeitswirkung,<br />

sowie eine stark politische Komponente. Könnten Sie kurz beschreiben, wie die Axpo Holding,<br />

respektive die Axpo AG in der Beziehungspflege mit den relevanten Akteuren vorgeht?<br />

26. Linthal 2015 ist ein Projekt mit grossen Auswirkungen auf die Natur und die Region. Die<br />

Projekteignerin KLL ist ein Partnerunternehmen des Kantons Glarus (15% Aktienanteil) und der<br />

Axpo AG (85% Aktienanteil). Ihr Sitz ist vor Ort in Linthal. Welche Aspekte sind aus Ihrer Sicht<br />

entscheidend gewesen, dass dieses Projekt mit der Unterstützung der Bevölkerung und<br />

verschiedenster Stakeholder realisiert werden kann?<br />

27. Welche Rolle spielt die Präsenz vor Ort durch den Firmensitz der KLL in Tierfehd, Linthal?<br />

28. Welche Rolle spielt die Region Linthal und der Kanton Glarus im Projekt? Nimmt die Region<br />

eine aktive Rolle ein, um die St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit des Projekts für Axpo AG/KKL attraktiv(er)<br />

zu machen?<br />

29. Gibt es ein weniger erfolgreiches Projekt, das Sie gut kennen? Was unterscheidet dieses Projekt<br />

Ihrer Ansicht nach am meisten vom Vorzeigeprojekt Linth-Limmern?<br />

30. Welche Punkte waren aus heutiger Sicht massgebend für die negative Entwicklung? Welches<br />

waren Ihrer Ansicht nach die entscheidenden Meilensteine?<br />

Wir kommen zum Schluss des Interviews.<br />

Gibt es etwas, was Sie gerne ergänzen möchten? Anmerkungen, Kommentare, oder Stichworte, die im<br />

bisherigen Gespräch nicht vorgekommen oder zu kurz gekommen sind?<br />

365


366<br />

Begrifflichkeitsklärungen<br />

Appendices<br />

Ressourcen Greifbare Ressourcen (tangibles) und Kompetenzen / Fähigkeiten<br />

(intangibles) eines Unternehmens.<br />

Risk bearing ability<br />

(Risikotragfähigkeit)<br />

Kritische Ressourcen können definiert werden als "firm-specific assets that<br />

are difficult if not impossible to imitate; examples are trade secrets <strong>and</strong><br />

certain specialized production facilities <strong>and</strong> engineering experience" [Quelle:<br />

Teece, D. J., Pisano, G., & Shuen, A. (1997). Dynamic Capabilities <strong>and</strong><br />

Strategic Management. Strategic Management Journal, 18(7), 509-533.]<br />

<strong>The</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> net income retained by the institution over time plus freely usable<br />

paid-in capital contributed by its shareholders minus special reserves divided<br />

by the sum <strong>of</strong> its risk assets<br />

Synergien Der gemeinsame Ertrag des Ganzen ist grösser als der Ertrag der Summe<br />

seiner Teile<br />

Corporate Management Synergien Leistungsvorteile von Unternehmen aus vorteilhaftem Einsatz ihrer<br />

Management-Ressourcen über das Gesamtgeschäft<br />

Cross-Business Synergien Der Wert, welcher über Zeit durch die Summe der Unternehmensteile<br />

geschaffen und erhalten (captured) wird, im Vergleich zum Wert dieser Teile<br />

als separate Einheiten<br />

Finanzielle Synergien Leistungsvorteile von Unternehmen aus vorteilhaftem Einsatz ihrer<br />

finanziellen Möglichkeiten über das Gesamtgeschäft<br />

Marktmacht-Synergien Leistungsvorteile von Unternehmen aus vorteilhaftem Einsatz ihrer<br />

Verh<strong>and</strong>lungsressourcen über das Gesamtgeschäft<br />

Operative Synergien Leistungsvorteile von Unternehmen aus vorteilhaftem Einsatz ihrer<br />

operativen Ressourcen über das Gesamtgeschäft<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ortgebundenheit<br />

(<strong>Location</strong>-fixity)<br />

Immobilität der eingesetzten Ressourcen, sowie starke lokale Einbettung des<br />

Unternehmens durch vielfältige Umfeld-Beziehungen.<br />

Beispiele dafür sind die Verbindung mit kritischen Zulieferern oder Kunden<br />

vor Ort, regulatorische und politische Vernetzung, sowie die Einbettung in<br />

die lokale Gemeinschaft.


Bibliography<br />

Bibliography<br />

A.T. Kearney. (2008). Airport Studie - Internationale Studienergebnisse. Retrieved<br />

March 8, 2010, from<br />

http://www.atkearney.at/content/veroeffentlichungen/whitepaper_practice.php/<br />

practice/aerospace/id/50052<br />

Aberle, G. (2003). Transportwirtschaft: Einzelwirtschaftliche und<br />

gesamtwirtschaftliche Grundlagen (4 ed.). Munich: Oldenbourg<br />

Wissenschaftsverlag.<br />

Achleitner, P. (1985). Sozio-politische Strategien multinationaler Untemehmungen.<br />

Bern.<br />

ACI. (2009). Policies <strong>and</strong> Recommended Practices H<strong>and</strong>book (7 ed., pp. 1-127).<br />

Geneva: Airports Council Interternational.<br />

ACI European Region, & York Consulting. (2000). Creating employment <strong>and</strong><br />

prosperity in Europe – An Economic impact study kit. Brussels: Airports<br />

Council International.<br />

Ack<strong>of</strong>f, R. (1974). <strong>The</strong> Social Responsibility <strong>of</strong> Operational Research. Operational<br />

Research Quarterly, 25(3), 361-371.<br />

AERA. (2009). White Paper - Regulatory Objectives <strong>and</strong> Philosophy in Economic<br />

Regulation <strong>of</strong> Airports <strong>and</strong> Air Navigation Services. New Delhi: Airports<br />

Economic Regulatory Authority <strong>of</strong> India.<br />

Akhter, S. (2007). Globalization, expectations model <strong>of</strong> economic nationalism, <strong>and</strong><br />

consumer behavior. Journal <strong>of</strong> Consumer Marketing, 24(3), 142 - 150.<br />

Akhter, S., Kim, D., & Hosseini, J. (2003). <strong>The</strong> influence <strong>of</strong> economic nationalism <strong>and</strong><br />

product quality on behavioral intentions: an empirical investigation. Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Global Business(Spring), 75-83.<br />

Alchian, A., & Woodward, S. (1988). Review: <strong>The</strong> Firm Is Dead; Long Live <strong>The</strong> Firm<br />

a Review <strong>of</strong> Oliver E. Williamson's <strong>The</strong> Economic Institutions <strong>of</strong> Capitalism.<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Economic Literature, 26(1), 65-79.<br />

Alderman, N. (2004). Mobility versus embeddedness: the role <strong>of</strong> proximity in major<br />

capital projects. In A. Lagendijk & P. Oinas (Eds.), Proximity, Distance <strong>and</strong><br />

Diversity: Issues on Economic Interaction <strong>and</strong> <strong>Local</strong> Development, Aldershot:<br />

Ashgate. Aldershot: Ashgate Publishing, Ltd.<br />

Amin, A. (2004). An institutionalist perspective on regional economic development. In<br />

T. Barnes, J. Peck & E. Sheppard (Eds.), Reading Economic Geography (pp.<br />

48–58). Oxford, UK: Blackwell Publishing.<br />

Amin, A., & Thrift, N. (1994). Living in the global. Oxford: Oxford University Press.<br />

Amit, R., & Schoemaker, P. (1993). Strategic assets <strong>and</strong> organizational rent. Strategic<br />

Management Journal, 14, 33-46.<br />

Amt für Verkehr. (2009). Eigentümerstrategie betreffend die Beteiligung des Kantons<br />

Zürich an der Flughafen Zürich AG. Zurich: Volkswirtschaftsdirektion des<br />

Kantons Zürich.<br />

Andrews, K. (1971). <strong>The</strong> Concept <strong>of</strong> Corporate Strategy. Homewood, Ill: Dow Jones-<br />

Irwin.<br />

367


368<br />

Bibliography<br />

Ans<strong>of</strong>f, H. (1965). Corporate strategy: an analytic approach to business policy for<br />

growth <strong>and</strong> expansion. New York: McGraw-Hill.<br />

Arrow, K. J. (1972). Gifts <strong>and</strong> Exchanges. Philosophy <strong>and</strong> Public Affairs, 1(4), 343-<br />

362 CR - Copyright &#169; 1972 Princeton University Press.<br />

Asher, C., Mahoney, J., & Mahoney, J. (2005). Towards a property rights foundation<br />

for a stakeholder theory <strong>of</strong> the firm. Journal <strong>of</strong> Management <strong>and</strong> Governance,<br />

9(1), 5-32.<br />

Axpo AG. (2009). Umweltdeklaration Kernkraftwerk Beznau. Baden.<br />

Axpo Holding AG. (2007). Die Axpo Nachhaltigkeitspolitik: Nachhaltigkeit -<br />

Verantwortung und Leistung (pp. 1-10). Baden: Axpo Holding AG.<br />

Axpo Holding AG. (2010a). Geschäftsbericht 2008 / 09. Baden, CH: Axpo Holding<br />

AG.<br />

Axpo Holding AG. (2010b). Nachhaltigkeitsbericht 2008/09 (pp. 1-67). Baden: Axpo<br />

Holding AG.<br />

Axpo Hydro Energie. (2009). Update Linthal 2015 - Newsletter der Kraftwerke Linth<br />

Limmern AG: Kraftwerke Linth-Limmern AG.<br />

Bacharach, S. (1989). Organizational theories: Some criteria for evaluation. <strong>The</strong><br />

Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 14(4), 496-515.<br />

Bansal, P., & Clell<strong>and</strong>, I. (2004). Talking trash: Legitimacy, impression management,<br />

<strong>and</strong> unsystematic risk in the context <strong>of</strong> the natural environment. Academy <strong>of</strong><br />

Management Journal, 47(1), 93-103.<br />

Barnes, T., & Gertler, M. (1999). Preface. In T. Barnes & M. Gertler (Eds.), <strong>The</strong> New<br />

Industrial Geography: Regions, Regulation <strong>and</strong> Institutions (pp. xv-xx).<br />

London: Routledge.<br />

Barney, J. (1991). Firm resources <strong>and</strong> sustained competitive advantage. Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

management, 17(1), 99-120.<br />

Barney, J. (1996). Gaining <strong>and</strong> sustaining competitive advantage. Reading, MA:<br />

Addison-Wesley.<br />

Barney, J., & Clark, D. (2007). Resource-based theory: creating <strong>and</strong> sustaining<br />

competitive advantage. New York: Oxford University Press.<br />

Barney, J., & Hoskisson, R. (1990). Strategic groups: Untested assertions <strong>and</strong> research<br />

proposals. Managerial <strong>and</strong> decision Economics, 11(3), 187-198.<br />

Bartlett, C., & Ghoshal, S. (1989). Managing Across Borders: <strong>The</strong> Transnational<br />

Solution. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.<br />

Bathelt, H., & Glueckler, J. (2003). Toward a relational economic geography. Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> Economic Geography, 3(2), 117-144.<br />

Baum, J., & Oliver, C. (1991). Institutional Linkages <strong>and</strong> Organizational Mortality.<br />

Administrative Science Quarterly, 36(2), 187-218.<br />

Bausch, A., & Raffeiner, T. (2003). Value Creators in der Utility-Industrie. Giessen:<br />

Accenture<br />

Justus-Liebig-Universität Giessen.<br />

Bazeley, P., & Richards, L. (2000). <strong>The</strong> NVIVO qualitative project book. London:<br />

Sage Publications.<br />

Becht, M., Bolton, P., & Röell, A. (2007). Corporate law <strong>and</strong> governance. In A.<br />

Polinsky & S. Shavell (Eds.), H<strong>and</strong>book <strong>of</strong> Law <strong>and</strong> Economics (Vol. 2, pp.<br />

829-943). North-Holl<strong>and</strong>: Elsevier.


Bibliography<br />

Becker-Blease, J., Goldberg, L., & Kaen, F. (2008). Mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions as a<br />

response to the deregulation <strong>of</strong> the electric power industry: value creation or<br />

value destruction? Journal <strong>of</strong> Regulatory Economics, 33(1), 21-53.<br />

Benkenstein, M. (1996). Qualitätsverbundbeziehungen zwischen unabhängigen<br />

Dienstleistungsanbietern. Die Betriebswirtschaft, 56, 777-789.<br />

Berg, A., & Gottschalg, O. (2005a). Underst<strong>and</strong>ing Value Creation in Buyouts.<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Restructuring Finance, 2, 9-37.<br />

Berg, A., & Gottschalg, O. (2005b). Underst<strong>and</strong>ing value generation in buyouts.<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Restructuring Finance, 1(2), 1-29.<br />

Berg, B. (2001). Qualitative Research Methods – For the Social Sciences (4 ed.).<br />

Harlow: Pearson.<br />

Besanko, D., Dranove, D., & Shanley, M. (2000). Economics <strong>of</strong> strategy. New York: J.<br />

Wiley.<br />

Birkelbach, R. (1993). Qualitätsmanagement in Dienstleistungscentern. Frankfurt<br />

a.M.: Lang.<br />

Bishara, A., & Schmitt, E. (2006). Consolidation in the Utility Industry: Cap Gemini.<br />

Bleisch, A. (2005). Die Erreichbarkeit von Regionen: Ein Benchmarking-Modell.<br />

Universität Basel, Basel.<br />

Boddewyn, J., & Brewer, T. (1994). International-Business Political Behavior: New<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical Directions. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 19(1), 119-143.<br />

Bogdan, R., & Biklen, S. (1982). Qualitative research for education: An introduction<br />

to theory <strong>and</strong> methods. Boston: Allyn <strong>and</strong> Bacon Inc.<br />

Bortz, J., & Döring, N. (2006). Forschungsmethoden und Evaluation für Human- und<br />

Sozialwissenschaftler (4 ed.). Heidelberg: Springer.<br />

Bosse, D., Phillips, R., & Harrison, J. (2009). Stakeholders, reciprocity, <strong>and</strong> firm<br />

performance. Strategic Management Journal, 30(4), 447-456.<br />

Bowen, F., Newenham-Kahindi, A., & Herremans, I. (2008). Engaging the<br />

Community: A Systematic Review, Knowledge Project Series (Vol. 1).<br />

Calgary: Research Network for Business Sustainability.<br />

Bower, J. (1974). Planning <strong>and</strong> control: bottom up or top down? Journal <strong>of</strong> General<br />

Management, 1(3), 20-31.<br />

Bowman, C., & Ambrosini, V. (2000). Value Creation Versus Value Capture:<br />

Towards a Coherent Definition <strong>of</strong> Value in Strategy. British Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Management, 11(1), 1-15.<br />

Bowman, C., & Ambrosini, V. (2007). Firm value creation <strong>and</strong> levels <strong>of</strong> strategy.<br />

Management Decision, 45(3), 360-371.<br />

Bowman, E. (1980). A risk/return paradox for strategic management. Sloan<br />

Management Review, 21(3), 17-31.<br />

Bowman, E., & Hurry, D. (1993). Strategy through the Option Lens: An Integrated<br />

View <strong>of</strong> Resource Investments <strong>and</strong> the Incremental-Choice Process. <strong>The</strong><br />

Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 18(4), 760-782.<br />

Branco, M., & Rodrigues, L. (2006). Corporate social responsibility <strong>and</strong> resourcebased<br />

perspectives. Journal <strong>of</strong> Business Ethics, 69(2), 111-132.<br />

Bromiley, P., Miller, K., & Rau, D. (2001). Risk in strategic management research. In<br />

R. Freeman, M. Hitt & J. Harrison (Eds.), <strong>The</strong> Blackwell H<strong>and</strong>book <strong>of</strong> Strategic<br />

Management (pp. 259-288). Oxford UK: Blackwell Publishers.<br />

369


370<br />

Bibliography<br />

Brown, C., & Lee, P. (2010). <strong>The</strong> changing pr<strong>of</strong>ile <strong>of</strong> airport investor. In M. Burns, E.<br />

Clayton & D. Schneiderbauer (Eds.), Aviation Infrastructure 2010 (pp. 3-10).<br />

London: Booz & Company Inc.<br />

Buchanan, J. (2001). Game theory, mathematics, <strong>and</strong> economics. Journal <strong>of</strong> Economic<br />

Methodology, 8(1), 27-32.<br />

Bulow, J., & Klemperer, P. (1999). <strong>The</strong> generalized war <strong>of</strong> attrition. American<br />

Economic Review, 175-189.<br />

Bundesamt für Energie. (2010). Schweizerische Elektrizitätsstatistik 2009. Bern: BFE.<br />

Bundesgesetz über die Luftfahrt, Bundesversammlung der Schweizerischen<br />

Eidgenossenschaft(1948).<br />

Burke, L., & Logsdon, J. (1996). How corporate social responsibility pays <strong>of</strong>f. Long<br />

Range Planning, 29(4), 495-502.<br />

Cadbury, A. (1992). Report <strong>of</strong> the committee on the financial aspects <strong>of</strong> corporate<br />

governance. London: Gee Publishing.<br />

Campbell, A., & Goold, M. (1995). <strong>The</strong> Value <strong>of</strong> the Parent Company. California<br />

Management Review, 38(1), 79-97.<br />

Campbell, A., & Goold, M. (2000). <strong>The</strong> collaborative enterprise: why links across the<br />

corporation <strong>of</strong>ten fail <strong>and</strong> how to make them work. New York: Basic Books.<br />

Campbell, J. (2007). Why would corporations behave in socially responsible ways? An<br />

institutional theory <strong>of</strong> corporate social responsibility. Academy <strong>of</strong> Management<br />

Review, 32(3), 946.<br />

Cantwell, J. (2009). <strong>Location</strong> <strong>and</strong> the multinational enterprise. Journal <strong>of</strong> International<br />

Business Studies, 40, 35-41.<br />

Carmeli, A. (2004). Assessing core intangible resources. European Management<br />

Journal, 22(1), 110-122.<br />

Caves, R.E. (1971). International Corporations: <strong>The</strong> Industrial Economics <strong>of</strong> Foreign<br />

Investment. Economica, 38(149), 1-27.<br />

Caves, R. E. (1998). Research on International Business: Problems <strong>and</strong> Prospects.<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> International Business Studies, 29(1), 5-19.<br />

Caves, R. E., & Ghemawat, P. (1992). Identifying Mobility Barriers. Strategic<br />

Management Journal, 13(1), 1-12.<br />

Chaffee, E. (1985). Three models <strong>of</strong> strategy. Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 10(1),<br />

89-98.<br />

Chatterjee, S. (1986). Types <strong>of</strong> synergy <strong>and</strong> economic value: <strong>The</strong> impact <strong>of</strong><br />

acquisitions on merging <strong>and</strong> rival firms. Strategic Management Journal, 7(2),<br />

119-139.<br />

Clark, G., & Wrigley, N. (1995). Sunk Costs: A Framework for Economic Geography.<br />

Transactions <strong>of</strong> the Institute <strong>of</strong> British Geographers, 20(2), 204-223.<br />

Clarkson, M. (1994). A Risk Based Model <strong>of</strong> Stakeholder <strong>The</strong>ory, Proceedings <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Second Toronto Conference on Stakeholder <strong>The</strong>ory. Toronto: Centre for<br />

Corporate Social Performance <strong>and</strong> Ethics, University <strong>of</strong> Toronto.<br />

Clarkson, M. (1995). A Stakeholder Framework for Analyzing <strong>and</strong> Evaluating<br />

Corporate Social Performance. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 20(1),<br />

92-117.<br />

Coase, R. (1937). <strong>The</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386-405.<br />

Coe, N., Kelly, P., & Yeung, H. (2007). Economic geography: a contemporary<br />

introduction. Oxford, UK: Blackwell Publishing.


Bibliography<br />

C<strong>of</strong>f, R. (1999). When competitive advantage doesn't lead to performance: <strong>The</strong><br />

resource-based view <strong>and</strong> stakeholder bargaining power. Organization Science,<br />

10(2), 119-133.<br />

Coleman, J. (1988). Social capital in the creation <strong>of</strong> human capital. American journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> sociology, 94(S1), 95-120.<br />

Collis, D., & Montgomery, C. (1995). Competing on Resources: Strategy in the 1990s.<br />

Harvard Business Review, 73(4), 118-128.<br />

commitment. (2009). In Merriam-Webster Online Dictionary. Retrieved November 27,<br />

2009, from http://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/commitment<br />

Commons, J. (1931). Institutional economics. American Economic Review, 21(4), 648-<br />

657.<br />

concession. (2010). In Merriam-Webster's online dictionary. Retrieved February 4,<br />

2010, from http://merriam-webster.com/dictionary/concession<br />

Conner, K. (1991). A historical comparison <strong>of</strong> resource-based theory <strong>and</strong> five schools<br />

<strong>of</strong> thought within industrial organization economics: do we have a new theory<br />

<strong>of</strong> the firm? Journal <strong>of</strong> Management, 17(1), 121-154.<br />

Cooper, S., & Owen, D. (2007). Corporate social reporting <strong>and</strong> stakeholder<br />

accountability: <strong>The</strong> missing link. Accounting, Organizations <strong>and</strong> Society, 32(7-<br />

8), 649-667.<br />

Corbin, J., & Strauss, A. (2008). Basics <strong>of</strong> qualitative research: Techniques <strong>and</strong><br />

Procedures for Developing Grounded <strong>The</strong>ory (3 ed.). Thous<strong>and</strong> Oaks, CA:<br />

Sage Publications.<br />

Cox, K. (1989). <strong>The</strong> politics <strong>of</strong> turf <strong>and</strong> the question <strong>of</strong> class. In J. Wolch & M. Dear<br />

(Eds.), <strong>The</strong> Power <strong>of</strong> Geography: How Territory Shapes Social Life (pp. 61-90).<br />

Boston: Unwin Hyman.<br />

Cox, K. (1995). Globalisation, competition <strong>and</strong> the politics <strong>of</strong> local economic<br />

development. Urban Studies, 32(2), 213-224.<br />

Cox, K. (1998a). <strong>Local</strong>ity <strong>and</strong> community: some conceptual issues. European<br />

Planning Studies, 6(1), 17-30.<br />

Cox, K. (1998b). Spaces <strong>of</strong> dependence, spaces <strong>of</strong> engagement <strong>and</strong> the politics <strong>of</strong><br />

scale, or: looking for local politics. Political Geography, 17(1), 1-23.<br />

Cox, K., & Mair, A. (1988). <strong>Local</strong>ity <strong>and</strong> community in the politics <strong>of</strong> local economic<br />

development (Vol. 78): Routledge.<br />

Creswell, J., & Miller, D. (2000). Determining validity in qualitative inquiry. <strong>The</strong>ory<br />

into practice, 39(3), 124-130.<br />

Crocker, K., & Masten, S. (1991). Pretia ex Machina? Prices <strong>and</strong> Process in Long-<br />

Term Contracts. Journal <strong>of</strong> Law <strong>and</strong> Economics, 34(1), 69-99.<br />

CSI. (2005). Environmental <strong>and</strong> social impact assessment (ESIA) guidelines: L<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> communities. Geneva: World Business Council for Sustainable<br />

Development.<br />

Curtis, S., Gesler, W., Smith, G., & Washburn, S. (2000). Approaches to sampling <strong>and</strong><br />

case selection in qualitative research: examples in the geography <strong>of</strong> health.<br />

Social Science & Medicine, 50(7-8), 1001-1014.<br />

Dacin, M., Ventresca, M., & Beal, B. (1999). <strong>The</strong> Embeddedness <strong>of</strong> Organizations:<br />

Dialogue & Directions. Journal <strong>of</strong> Management, 25(3), 317-356.<br />

Daft, R. (1983). Organizational <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>and</strong> Design. St. Paul, MN: West Publishing.<br />

371


372<br />

Bibliography<br />

Dale, B., & Nilsen, S. (2000, 19 -21 October). An Institutional Perspective on <strong>Local</strong><br />

Economic Development- the case <strong>of</strong> Raufoss. Paper presented at the Annual<br />

Conference: <strong>The</strong> Institutions <strong>of</strong> <strong>Local</strong> Development, Trento, IT.<br />

D<strong>and</strong>o, N., & Swift, T. (2003). Transparency <strong>and</strong> Assurance: Minding the Credibility<br />

Gap. Journal <strong>of</strong> Business Ethics, 44(2/3), 195-200.<br />

Datta, D. (1991). Organizational fit <strong>and</strong> acquisition performance: <strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> postacquisition<br />

integration. Strategic Management Journal, 12(4), 281-297.<br />

Davis, D., & Mentzer, J. (2008). Relational Resources in Interorganizational<br />

Exchange: <strong>The</strong> <strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> Trade Equity <strong>and</strong> Br<strong>and</strong> Equity. Journal <strong>of</strong> Retailing,<br />

84(4), 435-448.<br />

Davis, K. (1975). Five propositions for social responsibility. Business Horizons, 18(3),<br />

19-24.<br />

Davis, L., & North, D. (1971). Institutional Change <strong>and</strong> American Economic Growth:<br />

A First Step Towards a <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> Institutional Innovation. <strong>The</strong> Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Economic History, 30(1), 131-149.<br />

De Bakker, F., & den Hond, F. (2008). Introducing the Politics <strong>of</strong> Stakeholder<br />

Influence. Business & Society, 47(1), 8-20.<br />

Deephouse, D., & Carter, S. (2005). An Examination <strong>of</strong> Differences Between<br />

Organizational Legitimacy <strong>and</strong> Organizational Reputation. Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Management Studies, 42(2), 0022-2380.<br />

Demsetz, H. (2003). Ownership <strong>and</strong> the externality problem. In T. Anderson & T.<br />

McChesney (Eds.), Property Rights: Cooperation, Conflict, <strong>and</strong> Law (pp. 282-<br />

300). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.<br />

Denzin, N. (1978). <strong>The</strong> Research Act (2 ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill.<br />

Denzin, N., & Lincoln, Y. (2000). H<strong>and</strong>book <strong>of</strong> qualitative research (2 ed.). Thous<strong>and</strong><br />

Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.<br />

Denzin, N., & Lincoln, Y. (2003). <strong>The</strong> l<strong>and</strong>scape <strong>of</strong> qualitative research: <strong>The</strong>ories <strong>and</strong><br />

issues (2 ed.). Thous<strong>and</strong> Oaks, CA: Sage Publications, Inc.<br />

Dicken, P., & Malmberg, A. (2001). Firms in Territories: A Relational Perspective.<br />

Economic Geography, 77(4), 345-363.<br />

Dierickx, I., & Cool, K. (1989). Asset stock accumulation <strong>and</strong> sustainability <strong>of</strong><br />

competitive advantage. Management science, 35(12), 1504-1511.<br />

Dill, W. (1975). Public participation in corporate planning—strategic management in a<br />

Kibitzer's world. Long Range Planning, 8(1), 57-63.<br />

DiMaggio, P., & Powell, W. (1983). <strong>The</strong> Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional<br />

Isomorphism <strong>and</strong> Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields. American<br />

Sociological Review, 48(2), 147-160.<br />

DiMaggio, P., & Powell, W. (1991). Introduction. In W. Powell & P. DiMaggio<br />

(Eds.), <strong>The</strong> New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago:<br />

University <strong>of</strong> Chicago Press.<br />

Dixit, A., & Pindyck, R. (1994). Investment under uncertainty. Princeton, NJ:<br />

Princeton University Press.<br />

Dixit, A., & Pindyck, R. (1995). <strong>The</strong> options approach to capital investment. Harvard<br />

Business Review, May-June, 105-115.<br />

Domanico, F. (2007). Concentration in the European electricity industry: <strong>The</strong> internal<br />

market as solution? Energy Policy, 35(10), 5064-5076.


Bibliography<br />

Donaldson, T., & Preston, L. E. (1995). <strong>The</strong> Stakeholder <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> the Corporation:<br />

Concepts, Evidence, <strong>and</strong> Implications. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review,<br />

20(1), 65-91.<br />

Donath, J. (2007). Signals, cues <strong>and</strong> meaning.Unpublished manuscript.<br />

Dowling, J., & Pfeffer, J. (1975). Organizational Legitimacy: Social Values <strong>and</strong><br />

Organizational Behavior. <strong>The</strong> Pacific Sociological Review, 18(1), 122-136.<br />

Dranove, D., Peteraf, M., & Shanley, M. (1998). Do strategic groups exist? An<br />

economic framework for analysis. Strategic Management Journal, 19(11),<br />

1029-1044.<br />

Dudley, G. (1999). British Steel And Government Since Privatization: Policy<br />

'Framing' <strong>and</strong> the Transformation <strong>of</strong> Policy Networks. Public Administration,<br />

77(1), 51-71.<br />

Dunning, J. (2002). Relational assets, networks <strong>and</strong> international business activity. In<br />

F. Contractor & P. Lorange (Eds.), Cooperative Strategies <strong>and</strong> Alliances (pp.<br />

569–594). New York: Pergamon.<br />

Dunning, J. (2009). <strong>Location</strong> <strong>and</strong> the multinational enterprise: John Dunning's<br />

thoughts on receiving the Journal <strong>of</strong> International Business Studies 2008<br />

Decade Award. Journal <strong>of</strong> International Business Studies, 40(1), 20-34.<br />

Dyer, J. (1996). Specialized supplier networks as a source <strong>of</strong> competitive advantage:<br />

Evidence from the auto industry. Strategic Management Journal, 17, 271-291.<br />

Dyer, J., & Singh, H. (1998). <strong>The</strong> Relational View: Cooperative Strategy <strong>and</strong> Sources<br />

<strong>of</strong> Interorganizational Competitive Advantage. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management<br />

Review, 23(4), 660-679.<br />

Dyllick, T. (1984). Das Anspruchsgruppenkonzept: Eine Methodik zum Erfassen der<br />

Umweltbeziehungen der Unternehmung. io_Management-Zeitschrift, 53(2), 74-<br />

78.<br />

Dyllick, T. (1992). Management der Umweltbeziehungen–Öffentliche<br />

Ausein<strong>and</strong>esetzungen als Herausforderung (Vol. 2). Wiesbaden: Gabler.<br />

Dyllick, T. (2001). Soziale Nachhaltigkeit: Des Kaisers neue Kleider? In T. Bieker, M.<br />

Bilharz & C. Gminder (Eds.), Die soziale Dimension unternehmerischer<br />

Nachhaltigkeit, IWÖ-Diskussionsbeitrag Nr. 102. St.Gallen: IWÖ, Universität<br />

St. Gallen.<br />

Easterby-Smith, M., Thorpe, R., & Lowe, A. (1991). Management research: An<br />

introduction. London: Sage.<br />

Eberhardt, S. (1998). Wertorientierte Unternehmungsführung: der modifizierte<br />

Stakeholder-Value-Ansatz. Wiesbaden: Deutscher Universität Verlag.<br />

Eberl, M., & Schwaiger, M. (2005). Corporate reputation: disentangling the effects on<br />

financial performance. European Journal <strong>of</strong> Marketing, 39(7/8), 838-854.<br />

Eisenhardt, K. (1989). Building <strong>The</strong>ories from Case Study Research. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong><br />

Management Review, 14(4), 532-550.<br />

Eisenhardt, K., & Graebner, M. (2007). <strong>The</strong>ory building from cases: Opportunities <strong>and</strong><br />

challenges. Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Journal, 50(1), 25-32.<br />

Eisenhardt, K., & Martin, J. (2000). Dynamic capabilities: what are they? Strategic<br />

Management Journal, 21(10-11), 1105-1121.<br />

Eisenhardt, K., & Zbaracki, M. (1992). Strategic Decision Making. Strategic<br />

Management Journal, 13, 17-37.<br />

373


374<br />

Bibliography<br />

Falk, A., Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2008). Testing theories <strong>of</strong> fairness—Intentions<br />

matter. Games <strong>and</strong> Economic Behavior, 62, 287-303.<br />

Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Fairness <strong>and</strong> retaliation: <strong>The</strong> economics <strong>of</strong> reciprocity.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Journal <strong>of</strong> Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 159-181.<br />

Fehr, E., & Gintis, H. (2007). Human motivation <strong>and</strong> social cooperation: Experimental<br />

<strong>and</strong> analytical foundations. Annual Review <strong>of</strong> Sociology, 33, 43-64.<br />

Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. (1999). A theory <strong>of</strong> fairness, competition, <strong>and</strong> cooperation.<br />

Quarterly journal <strong>of</strong> Economics, 114(3), 817-868.<br />

Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. (2000). <strong>The</strong>ories <strong>of</strong> Fairness <strong>and</strong> Reciprocity: Evidence <strong>and</strong><br />

Economic Applications. Paper presented at the Advances in economics <strong>and</strong><br />

econometrics: theory <strong>and</strong> applications: eighth World Congress, Seattle.<br />

Ferner, A. (1988). Governments, Managers <strong>and</strong> Industrial Relations. Oxford: Basil<br />

Blackwell.<br />

Flick, U. (2007). Triangulation: Eine Einführung (2 ed.). Wiesbaden: VS Verlag.<br />

Flick, U. (2009). An introduction to qualitative research. Thous<strong>and</strong> Oaks, CA: Sage<br />

Publications.<br />

Flughafen Zürich AG. (2008). Sustainability Report. Zurich.<br />

Flughafen Zürich AG. (2009). International Airport Activities (pp. 1-9). Zurich.<br />

Flughafen Zürich AG. (2010). Annual Report (pp. 1-147). Zurich.<br />

Fombrun, C. (1996). Reputation: Realizing value from the corporate image: Harvard<br />

Business School Press.<br />

Fombrun, C., Gardberg, N., & Barnett, M. (2000). Opportunity Platforms <strong>and</strong> Safety<br />

Nets: Corporate Citizenship <strong>and</strong> Reputational Risk. Business <strong>and</strong> Society<br />

Review, 105(1), 85-106.<br />

Fombrun, C., & Shanley, M. (1990). What's in a Name? Reputation Building <strong>and</strong><br />

Corporate Strategy. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Journal, 33(2), 233-258.<br />

Fombrun, C., & Van Riel, C. (1997). <strong>The</strong> reputational l<strong>and</strong>scape. Corporate<br />

Reputation Review, 1(1/2), 5-13.<br />

Forsyth, P., Niemeier, H., & Wolf, H. (2011). Airport alliances <strong>and</strong> mergers -<br />

Structural change in the airport industry? Journal <strong>of</strong> Air Transport<br />

Management, 17(1), 49-56.<br />

Frank, D., & Riedl, P. (2004). <strong>The</strong>oretical Foundations <strong>of</strong> Contemporary Qualitative<br />

Market Research—An Overview <strong>and</strong> an Integrative Perspective. Retrieved 2, 5,<br />

from http://nbn-resolving.de/urn:nbn:de:0114-fqs0402307<br />

Freeman, R. (1984). Strategic management: A stakeholder approach. Boston, MA:<br />

Pitman Publishing.<br />

Freeman, R., & Reed, D. (1983). Stockholders <strong>and</strong> stakeholders: a new perspective on<br />

corporate governance. California Management Review, 25(3), 88-106.<br />

Friedman, M. (1962). Capitalism <strong>and</strong> Freedom. Chicago: University <strong>of</strong> Chicago Press.<br />

Frooman, J. (1999). Stakeholder Influence Strategies. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management<br />

Review, 24(2), 191-205.<br />

FT.com. (2009, December 30). Cement makers seek to spread risk. Retrieved March<br />

08, 2010, from http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/b63afb24-f4e2-11de-9cba-<br />

00144feab49a.html#ixzz19zwejj4Z<br />

Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (1987). Underst<strong>and</strong>ing Rent Dissipation: On the Use <strong>of</strong><br />

Game <strong>The</strong>ory in Industrial Organization. <strong>The</strong> American Economic Review,<br />

77(2), 176-183.


Bibliography<br />

Fuhrer, R. (2009, 27. November). Keine Bauverbote in Flughafengemeinden -<br />

Regierungsrätin Fuhrer zum ZFI-Massnahmenkonzept. NZZ Online.<br />

Furubotn, E., & Richter, R. (2005). Institutions <strong>and</strong> economic theory: <strong>The</strong> contribution<br />

<strong>of</strong> the new institutional economics. Ann Arbor: University <strong>of</strong> Michigan Press.<br />

Garriga, E., & Melé, D. (2004). Corporate social responsibility theories: mapping the<br />

territory. Journal <strong>of</strong> Business Ethics, 53(1), 51-71.<br />

Gesetz über den Flughafen Zürich, Kanton Zürich(1999).<br />

Getz, K. (2001). Public affairs <strong>and</strong> political strategy: theoretical foundations. Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> Public Affairs, 1(4), 305-329.<br />

Ghemawat, P., & Thomas, C. (2005). Multinational agglomeration in the cement<br />

industry: Patterns, drivers, <strong>and</strong> performance implications.Unpublished<br />

manuscript, Boston, MA.<br />

Ghemawat, P., & Thomas, C. (2008). Strategic interaction across countries <strong>and</strong><br />

multinational agglomeration: an application to the cement industry.<br />

Management Science, 54(12), 1980-1996.<br />

Ghoshal, S. (2005). Bad management theories are destroying good management<br />

practices. Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Learning & Education, 4(1), 75-91.<br />

Gil, N., & Beckman, S. (2009). Infrastructure Meets Business: Building New Bridges,<br />

Mending Old Ones. California Management Review, 51(2), 1-25.<br />

Glaser, B. (1992). Emergence vs forcing: Basics <strong>of</strong> grounded theory analysis. Mill<br />

Valley, CA: Sociology Press.<br />

Glaser, B., & Strauss, A. (1967). <strong>The</strong> discovery <strong>of</strong> grounded theory: Strategies for<br />

qualitative research. London: Wiedenfeld <strong>and</strong> Nicholson.<br />

Gnyawali, D., & Madhavan, R. (2001). Cooperative Networks <strong>and</strong> Competitive<br />

Dynamics: A Structural Embeddedness Perspective. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong><br />

Management Review, 26(3), 431-445.<br />

Goede, R., & De Villiers, C. (2003). <strong>The</strong> applicability <strong>of</strong> grounded theory as research<br />

methodology in studies on the use <strong>of</strong> methodologies in IS practices. In<br />

Proceedings <strong>of</strong> the 2003 annual research conference <strong>of</strong> the South African<br />

institute <strong>of</strong> computer scientists <strong>and</strong> information technologists on Enablement<br />

through technology (pp. 208-217): South African Institute for Computer<br />

Scientists <strong>and</strong> Information Technologists.<br />

Goold, M., & Campbell, A. (2000). Taking Stock <strong>of</strong> Synergy: A framework for<br />

assessing linkages between businesses. Long Range Planning, 33(1), 72-96.<br />

Goold, M., Campbell, A., & Alex<strong>and</strong>er, M. (1998). Corporate strategy <strong>and</strong> parenting<br />

theory. Long Range Planning, 31(2), 308-314.<br />

Gössling, T. (2004). Proximity, trust <strong>and</strong> morality in networks. European Planning<br />

Studies, 12(5), 675-689.<br />

Gossy, G. (2008). A Stakeholder Rationale for Risk Management: Implications for<br />

Corporate Finance Decisions. Wiesbaden: Gabler.<br />

Göthlich, S. (2003). Fallstudien als Forschungsmethode: Plädoyer für einen<br />

Methodenpluralismus in der deutschen betriebswirtschaftlichen Forschung.<br />

Kiel: Inst. für Betriebswirtschaftslehre.<br />

Gotsi, M., & Wilson, A. (2001). Corporate reputation: seeking a definition. Corporate<br />

Communications: An International Journal, 6(1), 24-30.<br />

Goulding, C. (1998). Grounded theory: the missing methodology on the interpretivist<br />

agenda. Qualitative Market Research: An International Journal, 1(1), 50-57.<br />

375


376<br />

Bibliography<br />

Goulding, C. (2002). Grounded <strong>The</strong>ory: A Practical Guide for Management, Business<br />

<strong>and</strong> Market Researchers (1 ed.). Thous<strong>and</strong> Oaks, CA: Sage Publications Inc.<br />

Government <strong>of</strong> Canada. (2007). Investment Canada Act, Related-Business Guidelines.<br />

Retrieved February 04, 2010, from http://www.ic.gc.ca/eic/site/icalic.nsf/eng/lk00064.html<br />

Goyal, A., & Santa-Clara, P. (2003). Idiosyncratic Risk Matters! <strong>The</strong> Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Finance, 58(3), 975-1007.<br />

Grabher, G. (1993). Rediscovering the Social in the Economics <strong>of</strong> Interfirm Relations.<br />

In G. Grabher (Ed.), <strong>The</strong> Embedded Firm (pp. 1-31). London: Routledge.<br />

Graf, M., H<strong>and</strong>l, K., & Pritzker, A. (2004). 1/3 Technik, 1/3 Politik, 1/3 Psychologie:<br />

20 Jahre REFUNA AG. Brugg: munda-Verlag.<br />

Graham, A. (2009). How important are commercial revenues to today's airports?<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Air Transport Management, 15(3), 106-111.<br />

Granovetter, M. (1973). <strong>The</strong> Strength <strong>of</strong> Weak Ties. <strong>The</strong> American Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Sociology, 78(6), 1360-1380.<br />

Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic Action <strong>and</strong> Social Structure: <strong>The</strong> Problem <strong>of</strong><br />

Embeddedness. <strong>The</strong> American Journal <strong>of</strong> Sociology, 91(3), 481-510.<br />

Greenspan, A. (1999). Harvard University Commencement Address. Cambridge, MA.<br />

Greenwood, M. (2007). Stakeholder engagement: Beyond the myth <strong>of</strong> corporate<br />

responsibility. Journal <strong>of</strong> Business Ethics, 74(4), 315-327.<br />

Grünig, P. (2009). Luftfahrtst<strong>and</strong>ort Schweiz - Kooperation zur Wirtschafts- und<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ortförderung Schweiz (presentation). Zurich: Flughafen Zürich AG.<br />

Guba, E., & Lincoln, Y. (1994). Competing Paradigms in Qualitative Research:<br />

<strong>The</strong>ories <strong>and</strong> Issues. In N. Denzin & Y. Lincoln (Eds.), H<strong>and</strong>book <strong>of</strong><br />

Qualitative Research (pp. 105-117). Thous<strong>and</strong> Oakes: Sage.<br />

Gubser, H., Zepf, N., Hubler, J., & Jochum, G. (2006). Studie Stromperspektiven<br />

2020: Strom für heute und morgen. Baden: Axpo Holding AG.<br />

Gulati, R. (1995). Social Structure <strong>and</strong> Alliance Formation Patterns: A Longitudinal<br />

Analysis. Administrative Science Quarterly, 40(4), 619-652.<br />

Gulati, R., Nohria, N., & Zaheer, A. (2000). Strategic networks. Strategic<br />

Management Journal, 21(3), 203-215.<br />

Haber, S., Maurer, N., & Razo, A. (2003). <strong>The</strong> politics <strong>of</strong> property rights: political<br />

instability, credible commitments, <strong>and</strong> economic growth in Mexico, 1876-1929.<br />

Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univ Press.<br />

Hall, R. (1993). A Framework Linking Intangible Resources <strong>and</strong> Capabiliites to<br />

Sustainable Competitive Advantage. Strategic Management Journal, 14(8),<br />

607-618.<br />

Hamilton, G. (1994). Civilizations <strong>and</strong> the organization <strong>of</strong> economies. In N. Smelser &<br />

R. Swedberg (Eds.), <strong>The</strong> h<strong>and</strong>book <strong>of</strong> economic sociology (pp. 183–205).<br />

Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.<br />

Hansen, M., & Nohria, N. (2004). How to build collaborative advantage. MIT Sloan<br />

Management Review, 46(1), 22-30.<br />

Hart, O., & Moore, J. (1990). Property Rights <strong>and</strong> the Nature <strong>of</strong> the Firm. <strong>The</strong> Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> Political Economy, 98(6), 1119-1158.<br />

Haspeslagh, P., & Jemison, D. (1991). <strong>The</strong> challenge <strong>of</strong> renewal through acquisitions.<br />

Strategy & Leadership, 19(2), 27-30.


Bibliography<br />

Hayter, R. (2004). Economic Geography as Dissenting Institutionalism: <strong>The</strong><br />

Embeddedness, Evolution <strong>and</strong> Differentiation <strong>of</strong> Regions. Geografiska<br />

Annaler: Series B, Human Geography, 86(2), 95-115.<br />

Hearit, K. (1995). “Mistakes were made”: Organizations, apologia, <strong>and</strong> crises <strong>of</strong> social<br />

legitimacy. Communication Studies, 46(1), 1-17.<br />

Helm, S. (2007). Unternehmensreputation und Stakeholder-Loyalitat. Wiesbaden:<br />

Deutscher Universitats-Verlag.<br />

Henisz, W., & Zelner, B. (1999). Political Risk <strong>and</strong> Infrastructure Investment. Paper<br />

presented at the Infrastructure for Development: Confronting Political <strong>and</strong><br />

Regulatory Risks, Rome.<br />

Henisz, W., & Zelner, B. (2005). Legitimacy, interest group pressures <strong>and</strong> change in<br />

emergent institutions: <strong>The</strong> case <strong>of</strong> foreign investors <strong>and</strong> host country<br />

governments. Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 30(2), 361-382.<br />

HGRS - CSR/SD Coordination. (2007). Fact Sheet - Mineral Components (pp. 2).<br />

Zurich: Holcim Group Support.<br />

HGRS - CSR/SD Coordination. (2008). Our SD Reporting Journey - Input UNGC<br />

meeting. Retrieved 18 March, 2010, from<br />

http://sportexx.de/docs/communication_on_progress/Geneva_2008/Holcim.pdf<br />

Hill, C. (1990). Cooperation, Opportunism, <strong>and</strong> the Invisible H<strong>and</strong>: Implications for<br />

Transaction Cost <strong>The</strong>ory. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 15(3), 500-<br />

513.<br />

Hill, C., Hitt, M., & Hoskisson, R. (1992). Cooperative versus competitive structures<br />

in related <strong>and</strong> unrelated diversified firms. Organization Science, 3(4), 501-521.<br />

Hill, C., & Jones, T. (1992). Stakeholder-Agency <strong>The</strong>ory. Journal <strong>of</strong> Management<br />

Studies, 29(2), 131-154.<br />

Hillman, A., & Hitt, M. (1999). Corporate Political Strategy Formulation: A Model <strong>of</strong><br />

Approach, Participation, <strong>and</strong> Strategy Decisions. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management<br />

Review, 24(4), 825-842.<br />

Hillman, A., & Keim, G. (2001). Shareholder Value, Stakeholder Management, <strong>and</strong><br />

Social Issues: What's the Bottom Line? Strategic Management Journal, 22(2),<br />

125-139.<br />

Hodgson, G. (2006). What are institutions? Journal <strong>of</strong> Economic Issues, 40(1), 1-25.<br />

H<strong>of</strong>fman, A. (2001). From heresy to dogma: An institutional history <strong>of</strong> corporate<br />

environmentalism. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.<br />

Holburn, G., & Spiller, P. (2002). Institutional or structural: lessons from international<br />

electricity sector reforms. In E. Brousseau & J. Glachant (Eds.), <strong>The</strong> Economics<br />

<strong>of</strong> Contracts: <strong>The</strong>ories <strong>and</strong> Applications (pp. 463-502). Cambridge, UK:<br />

Cambridge University Presse.<br />

Holcim. (2008). Corporate Sustainable Development Report 2007. Zurich: Holcim<br />

AG.<br />

Holcim. (2010). Corporate Sustainable Development Report 2009. Zurich: Holcim<br />

AG.<br />

Holcim (Schweiz) AG. (2008). Nachhaltigkeitsbericht: Fakten und Daten 2005–2007<br />

(pp. 1-52). Zurich: Holcim (Schweiz) AG.<br />

Holcim Ltd. (2004). Mission Statement (pp. 1-14). Jona: Holcim Ltd.<br />

Holcim Ltd. (2007a). Fact Sheet - Community Involvement. Zurich: Holcim Ltd.<br />

Holcim Ltd. (2007b). Fact Sheet - Stakeholder Relations. Zurich: Holcim Ltd.<br />

377


378<br />

Bibliography<br />

Holcim Ltd. (2009a). Community advisory panel in Albox - Holcim Spain. Retrieved<br />

14.12.2009, from<br />

http://www.holcim.com/CORP/EN/id/73138/mod//page/editorial.html<br />

Holcim Ltd. (2009b). Holcim at a glance. Jona: Holcim Ltd.<br />

Holcim Ltd. (2010a). Annual Report 2009 Holcim Ltd. Jona: Holcim Ltd.<br />

Holcim Ltd. (2010b). Corporate Social Responsibility Report 2009.<br />

Holcim Ltd. (2004). Mission Statement (pp. 1-14). Jona: Holcim Ltd.<br />

Holcim Ltd. (2007). Fact Sheet - Stakeholder Relations.<br />

Holcim Ltd. (2008). Corporate Social Responsibility Report 2007. Zurich: Holcim<br />

Ltd.<br />

Holcim Ltd. (2009). Holcim at a glance. Jona: Holcim Ltd.<br />

Holcim Ltd. (2010). Annual Report 2009 Holcim Ltd. Jona: Holcim Ltd.<br />

Höld, R. (2007). Zur Transkription von Audiodaten. In R. Buber & H. Holzmüller<br />

(Eds.), Qualitative Marktforschung (pp. 655-668). Wiesbaden: Gabler.<br />

Hosmer, L. (1995). Trust: <strong>The</strong> Connecting Link between Organizational <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>and</strong><br />

Philosophical Ethics. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 20(2), 379-403.<br />

Hunt, S., & Morgan, R. (1995). <strong>The</strong> Comparative Advantage <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> Competition.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Journal <strong>of</strong> Marketing, 59(2), 1-15.<br />

Husted, B. (2005). Risk management, real options, corporate social responsibility.<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Business Ethics, 60(2), 175-183.<br />

Hybels, R. (1995). On legitimacy, legitimation, <strong>and</strong> organizations: A critical review<br />

<strong>and</strong> integrative theoretical model. Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Journal, 38, 241-<br />

245.<br />

Infras. (2006). Volkswirtschaftliche Bedeutung der Luftfahrt in der Schweiz. Zürich:<br />

Aerosuisse, BAZL, Swiss International Airports Association.<br />

International Finance Corporation. (2007). Stakeholder Engagement: A Good Practice<br />

H<strong>and</strong>book for Companies Doing Business in Emerging Markets: IFC, World<br />

Bank Group.<br />

Jepperson, R., & Meyer, J. (1991). <strong>The</strong> public order <strong>and</strong> the construction <strong>of</strong> formal<br />

organizations. In W. Powell & P. DiMaggion (Eds.), <strong>The</strong> New Institutionalism<br />

in Organizational Analysis (pp. 1–38). Chicago: <strong>The</strong> University <strong>of</strong> Chicago<br />

Press.<br />

Joskow, P. (1988). Asset Specificity <strong>and</strong> the Structure <strong>of</strong> Vertical Relationships:<br />

Empirical Evidence. Journal <strong>of</strong> Law, Economics, & Organization, 4(1), 95-117.<br />

Joskow, P. (1991). <strong>The</strong> Role <strong>of</strong> Transaction Cost Economics in Antitrust <strong>and</strong> Public<br />

Utility Regulatory Policies. Journal <strong>of</strong> Law, Economics, & Organization, 7, 53-<br />

83.<br />

Jovanovic, M. (2009). Evolutionary economic geography: location <strong>of</strong> production <strong>and</strong><br />

the european union. London: Routledge.<br />

Karkkainen, B., Fung, A., & Sabel, C. (2000). After backyard environmentalism:<br />

Toward a performance-based regime <strong>of</strong> environmental regulation. American<br />

Behavioral Scientist, 44(4), 692.<br />

Keim, G., & Baysinger, B. (1988). <strong>The</strong> efficacy <strong>of</strong> business political activity:<br />

Competitive considerations in a principal-agent context. Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Management, 14(2), 163-180.


Bibliography<br />

Kessler, A., & Lülfesmann, C. (2006). <strong>The</strong> <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> Human Capital Revisited: on the<br />

Interaction <strong>of</strong> General <strong>and</strong> Specific Investments. <strong>The</strong> Economic Journal,<br />

116(514), 903-923.<br />

Klein, B. (1980). Transaction Cost Determinants <strong>of</strong> "Unfair" Contractual<br />

Arrangements. <strong>The</strong> American Economic Review, 70(2), 356-362.<br />

Klein, B., Crawford, R., & Alchian, A. (1978). Vertical integration, appropriable rents,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the competitive contracting process. Journal <strong>of</strong> Law <strong>and</strong> Economics, 21(2),<br />

297-326.<br />

Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1997). Does Social Capital Have An Economic Pay<strong>of</strong>f? A<br />

Cross-Country Investigation. Quarterly Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics, 112(4), 1251-<br />

1288.<br />

Knoll, S. (2008). Cross-business Synergies: A Typology <strong>of</strong> Cross-Business Synergies<br />

<strong>and</strong> a Mid-Range <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> Continuous Growth Synergy Realization.<br />

Wiesbaden: Gabler.<br />

Kochan, T., & Rubinstein, S. (2000). Toward a stakeholder theory <strong>of</strong> the firm: <strong>The</strong><br />

Saturn partnership. Organization Science, 367-386.<br />

Kocka, J. (2006). Civil Society in Historical Perspective. Berlin: Berghahn Books.<br />

Kogut, B. (1991). Joint Ventures <strong>and</strong> the Option to Exp<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Acquire. Management<br />

Science, 37(1), 19-33.<br />

Kogut, B., & Kulatilaka, N. (1994). Options thinking <strong>and</strong> platform investments:<br />

Investing in opportunity. California Management Review, 36(2), 52-71.<br />

Kogut, B., & Kulatilaka, N. (2001). Capabilities as Real Options. Organization<br />

Science, 12(6), 744-758.<br />

Kogut, B., & Z<strong>and</strong>er, U. (1992). Knowledge <strong>of</strong> the firm, combinative capabilities, <strong>and</strong><br />

the replication <strong>of</strong> technology. Organization science, 3(3), 383-397.<br />

Kostova, T., & Zaheer, S. (1999). Organizational legitimacy under conditions <strong>of</strong><br />

complexity: <strong>The</strong> case <strong>of</strong> the multinational enterprise. Academy <strong>of</strong> Management<br />

Review, 24(1), 64-81.<br />

Kromrey, H. (2006). Empirische Sozialforschung (12 ed.). Stuttgart: Lucius & Lucius.<br />

Krugman, P. (1998). What's new about the new economic geography? Oxford Review<br />

<strong>of</strong> Economic Policy, 14(2), 7-17.<br />

Kubicek, H. (1977). Heuristische Bezugsrahmen Heuristische Bezugsrahmen und<br />

heuristisch angelegte Forschungsdesigns als Elemente der<br />

Konstruktionsstrategie empirischer Forschung. In R. Koehler (Ed.), Empirische<br />

und h<strong>and</strong>lungstheoretische Forschungskonzeption in der<br />

Betriebswirtschaftslehre (pp. 3-36). Stuttgart: Poeschel Verlag.<br />

Kuhn, T. (1962). <strong>The</strong> structure <strong>of</strong> scientific revolutions. Chicago: University <strong>of</strong><br />

Chicago Press.<br />

KWO. (2009). KWO-Nachhaltigkeitsbericht 2008. Innertkirchen: Kraftwerke<br />

Oberhasli AG.<br />

Lamminmaki, D. (2005). Why do hotels outsource? An investigation using asset<br />

specificity. International Journal <strong>of</strong> Contemporary Hospitality Management,<br />

17(6), 516-528.<br />

Larson, A. (1992). Network Dyads in Entrepreneurial Settings: A Study <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Governance <strong>of</strong> Exchange Relationships. Administrative Science Quarterly,<br />

37(1), 76-104.<br />

379


380<br />

Bibliography<br />

Lavie, D. (2007). Alliance portfolios <strong>and</strong> firm performance: A study <strong>of</strong> value creation<br />

<strong>and</strong> appropriation in the US s<strong>of</strong>tware industry. Strategic Management Journal,<br />

28(12), 1187-1212.<br />

Lee, D., & Newby, H. (1983). <strong>The</strong> problem <strong>of</strong> sociology. London: Routledge.<br />

Lepak, D., Smith, K., & Taylor, M. (2007). Value creation <strong>and</strong> value capture: a<br />

multilevel perspective. Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 32(1), 180-194.<br />

Levy, B., & Spiller, P. (1996). A framework for resolving the regulatory problem. In<br />

B. Levy & P. Spiller (Eds.), Regulations, Institutions, <strong>and</strong> Commitment:<br />

Comparative studies <strong>of</strong> telecommunications (pp. 1). Cambridge, UK:<br />

Cambridge University Press.<br />

Lewis, S. (2001). Measuring corporate reputation. Corporate Communications: An<br />

International Journal, 6(1), 31-35.<br />

Lincoln, J., Hanada, M., & McBride, K. (1986). Organizational Structures in Japanese<br />

<strong>and</strong> U.S. Manufacturing. Administrative Science Quarterly, 31(3), 338-364.<br />

Lippman, S., & Rumelt, R. (1982). Uncertain imitability: An analysis <strong>of</strong> interfirm<br />

differences in efficiency under competition. <strong>The</strong> Bell Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics,<br />

13(2), 418-438.<br />

Litz, R. (1996). A resource-based-view <strong>of</strong> the socially responsible firm: Stakeholder<br />

interdependence, ethical awareness, <strong>and</strong> issue responsiveness as strategic assets.<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Business Ethics, 15(12), 1355-1363.<br />

Lohtia, R., Brooks, C., & Krapfel, R. (1994). What constitutes a transaction-specific<br />

asset? An examination <strong>of</strong> the dimensions <strong>and</strong> types. Journal <strong>of</strong> Business<br />

Research, 30, 261-270.<br />

LSE Centre for Civil Society. (2004). What is civil society? Retrieved 1 July, 2010,<br />

from http://www.lse.ac.uk/collections/CCS/what_is_civil_society.htm<br />

Lubatkin, M. (1983). Mergers <strong>and</strong> the Performance <strong>of</strong> the Acquiring Firm. <strong>The</strong><br />

Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 8(2), 218-225.<br />

Lubatkin, M., Lane, P., Collin, S., & Very, P. (2007). An embeddedness framing <strong>of</strong><br />

governance <strong>and</strong> opportunism: towards a cross-nationally accommodating theory<br />

<strong>of</strong> agency. Journal <strong>of</strong> Organizational Behavior, 28(1), 43-58.<br />

Lurati, G. (2009, 09 June). Städtischer Güterverkehr – die Position von Holcim<br />

(Presentation). Paper presented at the Städtischer Güterverkehr –<br />

H<strong>and</strong>lungsbedarf und Massnahmen in den Agglomerationen, Berne.<br />

Lustgarten, S., & Thomadakis, S. (1987). Mobility Barriers <strong>and</strong> Tobin's q. Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Business, 60(4), 519-537.<br />

Mabry, J. (1998). Regulation, Industry Structure, <strong>and</strong> Competitiveness in the US<br />

Portl<strong>and</strong> Cement. Business <strong>and</strong> Economic History, 27(2), 402-412.<br />

Macneil, I. (1980). Economic analysis <strong>of</strong> contractual relations: its shortfalls <strong>and</strong> the<br />

need for a rich classificatory apparatus. Northwestern University Law Review,<br />

75, 1018-1063.<br />

Mahoney, J. (2001). A resource-based theory <strong>of</strong> sustainable rents. Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Management, 27, 651-660.<br />

Mahoney, J., & P<strong>and</strong>ian, J. (1992). <strong>The</strong> resource-based view within the conversation<br />

<strong>of</strong> strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 13(5), 363-380.<br />

Maier, G., & Tödtling, F. (2006). Regional-und Stadtökonomik 1: St<strong>and</strong>orttheorie und<br />

Raumstruktur. Vienna: Springer.


Bibliography<br />

Makadok, R. (2001). Toward a synthesis <strong>of</strong> the resource-based <strong>and</strong> dynamic-capability<br />

views <strong>of</strong> rent creation. Strategic Management Journal, 22(5), 387-401.<br />

Markides, C., & Williamson, P. (1996). Corporate diversification <strong>and</strong> organizational<br />

structure: a resource-based view. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Journal, 39(2),<br />

340-367.<br />

Martin, J., & Eisenhardt, K. (2001). Exploring cross-business synergies, Academy <strong>of</strong><br />

Management 2001 Best Paper Proceedings.<br />

Martin, J., & Eisenhardt, K. (2002). Cross-business synergy: sources, processes, <strong>and</strong><br />

the capture <strong>of</strong> corporate value, Working Paper Series No. 3.<br />

Martin, J., & Eisenhardt, K. (2003). Cross-business synergy: Recombination,<br />

modularity <strong>and</strong> the multi-business team.Unpublished manuscript.<br />

Martin, R. (1994). Economic theory <strong>and</strong> human geography. In D. Gregory, R. Martin<br />

& G. Smith (Eds.), Human Geography: Society, Space, <strong>and</strong> Social Science (pp.<br />

21-53). London: Macmillan.<br />

Martin, R. (2003). Institutional approaches in economic geography. In E. Sheppard &<br />

T. Barnes (Eds.), A companion to economic geography (pp. 77–94). Oxford,<br />

UK: Blackwell Publishing.<br />

Mata, J. (1991). Sunk costs <strong>and</strong> entry by small <strong>and</strong> large plants. In P. Geroski & J.<br />

Schwalbach (Eds.), Entry <strong>and</strong> Market Contestability: An International<br />

Comparison (pp. 49-62). Oxford: Blackwell.<br />

Maurer, J. (1971). Readings in organization theory: open-system approaches. New<br />

York: R<strong>and</strong>om House.<br />

McBride, M. E. (1983). Spatial Competition <strong>and</strong> Vertical Integration: Cement <strong>and</strong><br />

Concrete Revisited. <strong>The</strong> American Economic Review, 73(5), 1011-1022.<br />

McGee, J., & Thomas, H. (1986). Strategic groups: theory, research <strong>and</strong> taxonomy.<br />

Strategic Management Journal, 7(2), 141-160.<br />

McLeod, G. (2004). Beyond S<strong>of</strong>t Institutionalism: Accumulation, Regulation, <strong>and</strong><br />

their Geographical Fixes. In A. Wood & D. Valler (Eds.), Governing <strong>Local</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

Regional Economies: Institutions, Politics <strong>and</strong> Economic Development.<br />

Aldershot: Ashgate Publishing.<br />

McNeil. (1974). <strong>The</strong> Many Futures <strong>of</strong> Contract. Southern California Law Review, 47,<br />

691-816.<br />

Meinefeld, W. (2004). Hypothesen und Vorwissen in der qualitativen Sozialforschung.<br />

In U. Flick, E. von Kardorff & I. Steinke (Eds.), Qualitative Forschung – Ein<br />

H<strong>and</strong>buch (pp. 265-275). Hamburg: Rowohlt,.<br />

Melé, D., & Guillén, M. (2006). <strong>The</strong> intellectual evolution <strong>of</strong> strategic management<br />

<strong>and</strong> its relationship with ethics <strong>and</strong> social responsibility, Working Paper (pp. 1-<br />

22). Navarra: IESE - University <strong>of</strong> Navarra.<br />

Ménard, C. (2004). <strong>The</strong> economics <strong>of</strong> hybrid organizations. Journal <strong>of</strong> Institutional<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>The</strong>oretical Economics, 160(3), 345-376.<br />

Ménard, C., & Shirley, M. (2005). H<strong>and</strong>book <strong>of</strong> New Institutional Economics.<br />

Dordrecht, NL: Springer.<br />

Meyer, J., & Rowan, B. (1977). Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as<br />

myth <strong>and</strong> ceremony. American journal <strong>of</strong> sociology, 83(2), 340-363.<br />

Meyer, J., & Rowan, B. (1991). Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as<br />

myth <strong>and</strong> ceremony, 41-62. <strong>The</strong> new institutionalism in organizational analysis,<br />

63-83.<br />

381


382<br />

Bibliography<br />

Michalisin, M., Smith, R., & Kline, D. (1997). In search <strong>of</strong> strategic assets.<br />

International Journal <strong>of</strong> Organizational Analysis, 5(4), 360-387.<br />

Migué, J. (1977). Controls versus subsidies in the economic theory <strong>of</strong> regulation.<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Law <strong>and</strong> Economics, 20(1), 213-221.<br />

Mikus, W. (1978). Industriegeographie. <strong>The</strong>men der allgemeinen Industrieraumlehre.<br />

Darmstadt: Wissenschaftliche Buchgesellschaft.<br />

Miles, M., & Huberman, A. (1994). Qualitative Data Analysis: An Exp<strong>and</strong>ed<br />

Sourcebook (2, illustrated ed.). Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications,.<br />

Miles, R., & Cameron, K. (1982). C<strong>of</strong>fin nails <strong>and</strong> corporate strategies. Englewood<br />

Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.<br />

Miller, K., & Bromiley, P. (1990). Strategic Risk <strong>and</strong> Corporate Performance: An<br />

Analysis <strong>of</strong> Alternative Risk Measures. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Journal,<br />

33(4), 756-779.<br />

Mintzberg, H. (1983). Power In <strong>and</strong> Around Organizations. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:<br />

Prentice Hall.<br />

Mitchell, R., Agle, B., & Wood, D. (1997). Toward a <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> Stakeholder<br />

Identification <strong>and</strong> Salience: Defining the Principle <strong>of</strong> Who <strong>and</strong> What Really<br />

Counts. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 22(4), 853-886.<br />

Mjøset, L. (1985). Regulation <strong>and</strong> the Institutionalist Tradition. In L. Mjøset & J.<br />

Bohlin (Eds.), Introduksjon til Reguleringskolen: Tre Arbeidsnotater (pp. 1–<br />

101). Aalborgm: Noordisk Soomeruniversitet.<br />

Mohrman, A., & Lawler, E. (1985). <strong>The</strong> diffusion <strong>of</strong> QWL as a paradigm shift. Los<br />

Angeles: Graduate School <strong>of</strong> Business Administration,, University <strong>of</strong> Southern<br />

California.<br />

Moldaschl, M., & Fischer, D. (2004). Beyond the Management View: A Ressource-<br />

Centered Socio-Economic Perspective. management revue. <strong>The</strong> International<br />

Review <strong>of</strong> Management Studies, 15(1), 122-151.<br />

Morsches, G., Gell, J., Finger, M., Seshadri, P., & Peters, R. (2008). Utility Mergers<br />

<strong>and</strong> Acquisitions: Beating the Odds. UtilitiesProject, 2010, 113-116.<br />

Morse, J. (1994). Critical issues in qualitative research methods. Thous<strong>and</strong> Oaks, CA:<br />

Sage Publications, Inc.<br />

Morse, J., Barrett, M., Mayan, M., Olson, K., & Spiers, J. (2002). Verification<br />

strategies for establishing reliability <strong>and</strong> validity in qualitative research.<br />

International Journal <strong>of</strong> Qualitative Methods, 1(2), 1-13.<br />

Morse, J., & Richards, L. (2002). Readme first for a user's guide to qualitative<br />

methods. Thous<strong>and</strong> Oaks, CA: Sage Publications,.<br />

Müller-Jentsch, D. (2009). Nationale Infrastruktur im föderalen Geflecht: Der<br />

Dauerkonflikt um den Flughafen Zürich. Zurich: Avenir Suisse.<br />

Müller-Stewens, G., & Lechner, C. (2002). Unternehmensindividuelle und<br />

gastl<strong>and</strong>bezogene Einflussfaktoren der Markteintrittsform. In K. Macharzina &<br />

M. Oesterle (Eds.), H<strong>and</strong>buch Internationales Management. Grundlagen -<br />

Instrumente - Perspektiven (2 ed., pp. 381-402). Wiesbaden: Gabler.<br />

Müller-Stewens, G., & Lechner, C. (2005). Strategisches Management: Wie<br />

strategische Initiativen zum W<strong>and</strong>el führen. Stuttgart: Schaeffer-Poeschel,.<br />

N.N. (2007, 02. May). Der Duft der grossen weiten Welt. Cash, p. 6.<br />

N.N. (2004). Independent Refiners <strong>and</strong> Marketers Spin the Value Wheel - Strategies<br />

for Sustaining Long-Term Growth: A.T. Kearney,.


Bibliography<br />

N.N. (2006, February 23). Merger hypocrites kill EU champs at birth. Retrieved<br />

February 27, 2010, from<br />

http://www.europeanvoice.com/article/imported/merger-hypocrites-kill-euchamps-at-birth/54191.aspx<br />

Nag, R., Hambrick, D., & Chen, M. (2007). What is strategic management, really?<br />

Inductive derivation <strong>of</strong> a consensus definition <strong>of</strong> the field. Strategic<br />

Management Journal, 28(9), 935-955.<br />

Nahapiet, J., & Ghoshal, S. (1998). Social Capital, Intellectual Capital, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Organizational Advantage. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 23(2), 242-<br />

266.<br />

Nayyar, P. (1990). Information Asymmetries: A Source <strong>of</strong> Competitive Advantage for<br />

Diversified Service Firms. Strategic Management Journal, 11(7), 513-519.<br />

Neu, D., Warsame, H., & Pedwell, K. (1998). Managing public impressions:<br />

environmental disclosures in annual reports. Accounting, Organizations <strong>and</strong><br />

Society, 23(3), 265-282.<br />

Newbery, D. (2003). Privatising Network Industries. Paper presented at the CESifo<br />

Conference on Privatisation Experiences in the EU.<br />

Newmark, C. (1998). Price <strong>and</strong> seller concentration in cement: effective oligopoly or<br />

misspecified transportation cost? Economics Letters, 60(2), 243-250.<br />

Niedergesäss, U., & Rettberg, B. (1998). Unternehmensdialoge in der Einschätzung<br />

von Experten aus Wirtschaft, Wissenschaft und NGOs. Hannover: Universität<br />

Hannover, Institut für Betriebsforschung.<br />

Nilsen, Ø., Raknerud, A., Rybalka, M., & Skjerpen, T. (2005). Lumpy Investments,<br />

Factor Adjustments <strong>and</strong> Productivity.Unpublished manuscript, Bergen.<br />

Nooteboom, B. (1996). Trust, Opportunism <strong>and</strong> Governance: A Process <strong>and</strong> Control<br />

Model. Organizational Studies, 17(6), 985-1010.<br />

Nooteboom, B. (2004). Inter-firm collaboration, learning <strong>and</strong> networks: an integrated<br />

approach. London: Routledge.<br />

Nooteboom, B. (2007). Service value chains <strong>and</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> scale. Service Business,<br />

1(2), 119-139.<br />

Nooteboom, B., Berger, H., & Noorderhaven, N. (1997). <strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> trust <strong>and</strong><br />

governance on relational risk. Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Journal, 308-338.<br />

Normann, R., & Ramirez, R. (1993). Designing interactive strategy. Harvard Business<br />

Review, 65-77.<br />

North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, <strong>and</strong> economic performance.<br />

Cambridge: Cambridge Univ Press.<br />

North, D. (1992). Institutions <strong>and</strong> economic theory. American Economist, 36(1), 3-6.<br />

NZZ Online. (13 September 2010). Venezuela entschädigt Holcim. Retrieved 01<br />

November, 2010, from<br />

http://www.nzz.ch/nachrichten/zuerich/venezuela_holcim_entschaedigung_650<br />

_millionen_dollar_1.7537375.html<br />

OECD. (2007). Infrastructure to 2030: Mapping Policy for Electricity, Water <strong>and</strong><br />

Transport (Vol. 2). Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation <strong>and</strong><br />

Development.<br />

Oinas, P. (1995). Organizations <strong>and</strong> Environments: Linking Industrial Geography <strong>and</strong><br />

Organization <strong>The</strong>ory Spatial Perspectives. In S. Conti, E. Malecki & P. Oinas<br />

383


384<br />

Bibliography<br />

(Eds.), <strong>The</strong> Industrial Enterprise <strong>and</strong> its Environment (pp. 143-170). Aldershot:<br />

Avebury.<br />

Oinas, P. (1997). On the socio-spatial embeddedness <strong>of</strong> business firms. Erdkunde,<br />

51(1), 23-32.<br />

Oinas, P. (1998). <strong>The</strong> embedded firm? prelude for a revived geography <strong>of</strong> enterprise.<br />

Helsinki: Helsinki School <strong>of</strong> Economics <strong>and</strong> Business Administration.<br />

Oinas, P. (1999a). Unpacking `embeddedness': Mimeo.<br />

Oinas, P. (1999b). Voices <strong>and</strong> silences: the problem <strong>of</strong> access to embeddedness.<br />

Ge<strong>of</strong>orum, 30(4), 351-361.<br />

Oliver, C. (1997). Sustainable Competitive Advantage: Combining Institutional <strong>and</strong><br />

Resource-Based Views. Strategic Management Journal, 18(9), 697-713.<br />

Oliver, C., & Holzinger, I. (2008). <strong>The</strong> effectiveness <strong>of</strong> strategic political<br />

management: A dynamic capabilities framework. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management<br />

Review (AMR), 33(2), 496-520.<br />

Orlitzky, M., & Benjamin, J. (2001). Corporate social performance <strong>and</strong> firm risk: a<br />

meta-analytic review. Business & Society, 40(4), 369-396.<br />

Otto, S. (2006). Cement Manufacture <strong>and</strong> Sustainability: Global Issue, <strong>Local</strong><br />

Solutions. Retrieved 22.07.2009, 2009, from<br />

http://www.ucs.iastate.edu/mnet/_repository/2006/betterconcrete/pdf/Otto%20-<br />

%20Cement%20Manufacture%20<strong>and</strong>%20Sustainability.pdf<br />

Parker, D. (2003). Performance, risk <strong>and</strong> strategy in privatised, regulated industries.<br />

International Journal <strong>of</strong> Public Sector Management, 16(1), 75–100.<br />

Parsons, T. (1960). Structure <strong>and</strong> Process in Modern Society. New York: John Wiley.<br />

Patton, M. (1990). Qualitative Evaluation <strong>and</strong> Research Methods: A Systematic<br />

Approach. Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications.<br />

Penrose, E. (1959). <strong>The</strong> <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> the Growth <strong>of</strong> the Firm. New York: Oxford<br />

University Press.<br />

Peteraf, M. (1993). <strong>The</strong> cornerstones <strong>of</strong> competitive advantage: a resource-based view.<br />

Strategic Management Journal, 14(3), 179-191.<br />

Peteraf, M. (2005). A Resource-Based Lens on Value Creation, Competitive<br />

Advantage, <strong>and</strong> Multi-Level Issues in Strategic Management Research. Multilevel<br />

issues in strategy <strong>and</strong> methods, 4, 177-188.<br />

Peteraf, M., & Barney, J. (2003). Unraveling the Resource-Based Tangle. Managerial<br />

<strong>and</strong> Decision Economics, 24(4), 309-323.<br />

Pfeffer, J. (1972). Size <strong>and</strong> Composition <strong>of</strong> Corporate Boards <strong>of</strong> Directors: <strong>The</strong><br />

Organization <strong>and</strong> its Environment. Administrative Science Quarterly, 17(2),<br />

218-228.<br />

Pfeffer, J. (1981). Power in organizations. Cambridge, MA: Pitman Publishing.<br />

Phillips, R. (2003). Stakeholder Legitimacy. Business Ethics Quarterly, 13(1), 25-41.<br />

Phillips, R., & Reichart, J. (2000). <strong>The</strong> environment as a stakeholder: A fairness-based<br />

approach. Journal <strong>of</strong> Business Ethics, 23(2), 185-197.<br />

Pidgeon, N. (2002). Grounded <strong>The</strong>ory: <strong>The</strong>oretical Background. In J. Richardson & B.<br />

Publishers (Eds.), H<strong>and</strong>book <strong>of</strong> qualitative research methods for psychology<br />

<strong>and</strong> the social sciences (pp. 75-85). Oxford, UK: Blackwell Publishing.<br />

Pies, I. (2001). Transaktion versus Interaktion, Spezifität versus Brisanz und die raison<br />

d'être korporativer Akteure: zur konzeptionellen Neuausrichtung der


Bibliography<br />

Organisationsökonomik. In I. Pies & M. Leschke (Eds.), Oliver Williamsons<br />

Organisationsökonomik (pp. 95-119). Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.<br />

Pike, A., Lagendijk, A., & Vale, M. (2000). Critical reflections on 'embeddedness' in<br />

economic geography: labour market governance in the North East region <strong>of</strong><br />

Engl<strong>and</strong>. In A. Giunta, A. Lagendijk & A. Pike (Eds.), Restructuring industry<br />

<strong>and</strong> territory: the experience <strong>of</strong> Europe’s regions (pp. 59-82). London: TSO.<br />

Polanyi, K. (1944). <strong>The</strong> Great Transformation. <strong>The</strong> Political <strong>and</strong> Economic Origins <strong>of</strong><br />

Our Time. New York,: Rinehart.<br />

Polanyi, M. (1962). Personal Knowledge: Towards a Post-critical Philosophy.<br />

Chicago, IL: Chicago University Press.<br />

Popper, K. (1976). Logik der Forschung. Tübingen: Mohr (Siebeck),.<br />

Poppo, L., & Zenger, T. (2002). Do formal contracts <strong>and</strong> relational governance<br />

function as substitutes or complements? Strategic Management Journal, 23(8),<br />

707-725.<br />

Porter, M. (1979). <strong>The</strong> structure within industries <strong>and</strong> companies' performance. <strong>The</strong><br />

Review <strong>of</strong> Economics <strong>and</strong> Statistics, 61(2), 214-227.<br />

Porter, M. (1985). Competitive Advantage: Creating <strong>and</strong> Sustaining Superior<br />

Performance. New York: Free Press.<br />

Porter, M. (1998). Clusters <strong>and</strong> the new economics <strong>of</strong> competition. Harvard business<br />

review, 76(6), 77-90.<br />

Post, J., Preston, L., & Sachs, S. (2002a). Managing the extended enterprise: <strong>The</strong> new<br />

stakeholder view. California Management Review, 45(1), 6-28.<br />

Post, J., Preston, L., & Sachs, S. (2002b). Redefining the Corporation: Stakeholder<br />

Management <strong>and</strong> Organizational Wealth. Stanford: Stanford University Press.<br />

Priem, R. (2001). "<strong>The</strong>" Business-Level RBV: Great Wall or Berlin Wall? <strong>The</strong><br />

Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 26(4), 499-501.<br />

Punch, K. (2000). Developing Effective Research Proposals. London: Sage<br />

Publications.<br />

Punch, K. (2005). Introduction to social research: Quantitative <strong>and</strong> qualitative<br />

approaches. London: Sage Publications Inc.<br />

PWC. (2009). Power Deals: Mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions activity within the global<br />

electricity <strong>and</strong> gas market, Annual Review 2009 (pp. 1-17):<br />

PricewaterhouseCoopers International Limited.<br />

Ramamurti, R. (2003). Can governments make credible promises? Insights from<br />

infrastructure projects in emerging economies. Journal <strong>of</strong> International<br />

Management, 9(3), 253-269.<br />

Ray, S. (2003). Strategic adaptation <strong>of</strong> firms during economic liberalisation: Emerging<br />

issues <strong>and</strong> a research agenda. International Journal <strong>of</strong> Management, 20(3), 271-<br />

281.<br />

Ray, S., & Ramakrishnan, K. (2005). Resources, Competences <strong>and</strong> Capabilities<br />

Conundrum: A Back-to-Basics Call.Unpublished manuscript, Calcutta.<br />

Reason, P., & Rowan, J. (1981). Human inquiry: A sourcebook <strong>of</strong> new paradigm<br />

research. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons.<br />

Ricardo, D. (1821). <strong>The</strong> Principles <strong>of</strong> Political Economy <strong>and</strong> Taxation (3rd ed.).<br />

Rutl<strong>and</strong>, Vermont: Charles E. Tuttle Co. Inc.<br />

385


386<br />

Bibliography<br />

Richter, R. (2001, September 13–15). New economic sociology <strong>and</strong> new institutional<br />

economics. Paper presented at the Annual Conference <strong>of</strong> the International<br />

Society for New Institutional Economics (ISNIE), Berkeley, CA.<br />

Richter, R., & Furubotn, E. (2003). Neue Institutionenökonomik: Eine Einführung und<br />

kritische Würdigung (3 ed.). Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.<br />

Riege, A. (2003). Validity <strong>and</strong> reliability tests in case study research: a literature<br />

review with'h<strong>and</strong>s-on' applications for each research phase. Qualitative Market<br />

Research: An International Journal, 6(2), 75-86.<br />

Robins, J. (1987). Organizational Economics: Notes on the Use <strong>of</strong> Transaction-Cost<br />

<strong>The</strong>ory in the Study <strong>of</strong> Organizations. Administrative Science Quarterly, 32(1),<br />

68-86.<br />

Röglin, H.-C. (1994). Technikängste und wie man damit umgeht. Düsseldorf: VDI<br />

Verlag GmbH.<br />

Rosenzweig, P., & Singh, J. (1991). Organizational Environments <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Multinational Enterprise. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 16(2), 340-361.<br />

Ross, E. (1896). <strong>The</strong> location <strong>of</strong> industries. <strong>The</strong> Quarterly Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics,<br />

10(3), 247-268.<br />

Rowley, T., Behrens, D., & Krackhardt, D. (2000). Redundant governance structures:<br />

An analysis <strong>of</strong> structural <strong>and</strong> relational embeddedness in the steel <strong>and</strong><br />

semiconductor industries. Strategic Management Journal, 21, 369-386.<br />

Ruefli, T., Collins, J., & Lacugna, J. (1999). Risk measures in strategic management<br />

research: auld lang syne? Strategic Management Journal, 20(2), 167-194.<br />

Rugman, A., & Verbeke, A. (2001). Subsidiary-specific advantages in multinational<br />

enterprises. Strategic Management Journal, 22(3), 237-250.<br />

Ruigrok, W., & Wagner, H. (2003). Internationalization <strong>and</strong> performance: an<br />

organizational learning perspective. Management International Review, 43(1),<br />

63-84.<br />

Rumelt, R. (1974). Strategy, structure, <strong>and</strong> economic performance. Boston, MA:<br />

Harvard University Press.<br />

Rumelt, R. (1984). Towards a strategic theory <strong>of</strong> the firm. In R. Lamb (Ed.),<br />

Resources, firms, <strong>and</strong> strategies: A reader in the resource-based perspective<br />

(pp. 556-570). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.<br />

Rumelt, R. (2003). What in the world is competitive advantage, Policy Working Paper<br />

105 (pp. 1-5).<br />

Sanchez, R. (1993). Strategic flexibility, firm organization, <strong>and</strong> managerial work in<br />

dynamic markets: a strategic options perspective. Advances in Strategic<br />

Management, 9(1993), 251-291.<br />

Sangiorgio, C., Hottinger, S., & Brodbeck, B. (2008). Risikoaggregation in der Praxis<br />

des Axpo-Konzerns. In D. G. f. Risikomanagement (Ed.), Risikoaggregation in<br />

der Praxis. Berlin: Springer.<br />

Schedler, K., & Bieger, T. (2002). Falken und Spatzen im Markt der (halb-)<br />

öffentlichen Leistungen. Der'Service Public'als international hart umkämpftes<br />

Geschäft. In C. Kaspar, C. Laesser & T. Bieger (Eds.), Jahrbuch 2001/2002<br />

Schweizerische Verkehrswirtschaft (pp. 79–88). St. Gallen: IDT (University <strong>of</strong><br />

St. Gallen).<br />

Schedler, K., Gulde, A., & Suter, S. (2007). Corporate Governance öffentlicher<br />

Unternehmen - Ausgewählte Fragen zur Führung staatlicher Beteiligungen. St.


Bibliography<br />

Gallen: Institut für Öffentliche Dienstleistungen und Tourismus der Universität<br />

St. Gallen.<br />

Scott, W. (2001). Institutions <strong>and</strong> Organizations (Foundations for Organizational<br />

Science) (2 ed.). Thous<strong>and</strong> Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.<br />

Scott, W., Ruef, M., Mendel, P., & Caronna, C. (2000). Institutional change <strong>and</strong><br />

organizations: Transformation <strong>of</strong> a healthcare field. Chicago: University<br />

Chicago Press.<br />

Seeger, M., Sellnow, T., & Ulmer, R. (1998). Communication, organization, <strong>and</strong><br />

crisis. In M. Rol<strong>of</strong>f (Ed.), Communication Yearbook (Vol. 21, pp. 231-276).<br />

Thous<strong>and</strong> Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.<br />

Selznick, P. (1985). Focusing organisational research on regulation. In R. Noll (Ed.),<br />

Regulatory Policy <strong>and</strong> the Social Sciences. Berkeley: University <strong>of</strong> California<br />

Press.<br />

Shaffer, B. (1995). Firm-level responses to government regulation: <strong>The</strong>oretical <strong>and</strong><br />

research approaches. Journal <strong>of</strong> Management, 21(3), 495-514.<br />

Shaffer, B., & Hillman, A. (2000). <strong>The</strong> development <strong>of</strong> business-government strategies<br />

by diversified firms. Strategic Management Journal, 21(2), 175-190.<br />

Shapiro, S. (1987). <strong>The</strong> Social Control <strong>of</strong> Impersonal Trust. <strong>The</strong> American Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Sociology, 93(3), 623-658.<br />

Shocker, A., & Sethi, S. (1973). An approach to incorporating societal preferences in<br />

developing corporate social action. California Management Review(Summer),<br />

97-105.<br />

Simon, H. (1961). Administrative behavior. A study <strong>of</strong> decision-making processes in<br />

administrative organization (2 ed.). New York: McMillan.<br />

Singh, H., & Montgomery, C. (1987). Corporate Acquisition Strategies <strong>and</strong> Economic<br />

Performance. Strategic Management Journal, 8(4), 377-386.<br />

Sirmon, D., Hitt, M., & Irel<strong>and</strong>, R. (2007). Managing firm resources in dynamic<br />

environments to create value: Looking inside the black box. Academy <strong>of</strong><br />

Management Review, 32(1), 273-292.<br />

Smelser, N., & Swedberg, R. (2005). <strong>The</strong> H<strong>and</strong>book <strong>of</strong> Economic Sociology (2 ed.).<br />

Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.<br />

Smith, A. (1776). Wealth <strong>of</strong> nations. London: Methuen <strong>and</strong> Co.<br />

Spence, M. (2002). Signaling in Retrospect <strong>and</strong> the Informational Structure <strong>of</strong><br />

Markets. <strong>The</strong> American Economic Review, 92(3), 434-459.<br />

Spiller, P., & Tommasi, M. (2005). <strong>The</strong> Institutions <strong>of</strong> Regulation. In C. Menard & M.<br />

Shirley (Eds.), H<strong>and</strong>book <strong>of</strong> New Institutional Economics (pp. 515–543).<br />

Dordrecht, NL: Springer.<br />

Staatskanzlei Kanton Glarus. (2007). Aus den Verh<strong>and</strong>lungen des Regierungsrates<br />

vom 12. Juni 2007 - Volkswirtschaftliche Auswikungen des Projekts "Linthal<br />

2015". Glarus: Kanton Glarus.<br />

Stablein, R. (1996). Data in organization studies. In S. Glegg, C. Hardy & W. Nord<br />

(Eds.), H<strong>and</strong>book <strong>of</strong> Organization Studies (pp. 509-529). Thous<strong>and</strong> Oaks, CA:<br />

Sage Publications.<br />

Stake, R. (1995). <strong>The</strong> art <strong>of</strong> case study research. London: Sage Publications.<br />

Stiglitz, J., & Heertje, A. (1989). <strong>The</strong> economic role <strong>of</strong> the state. Oxford: Blackwell<br />

Publishing.<br />

387


388<br />

Bibliography<br />

Storper, M. (1997). <strong>The</strong> regional world: territorial development in a global economy.<br />

New York: <strong>The</strong> Guilford Press.<br />

Strauss, A., & Corbin, J. (1990). Basics <strong>of</strong> qualitative research: Grounded theory<br />

procedures <strong>and</strong> techniques. Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications.<br />

Suchman, M. (1995). Managing legitimacy: Strategic <strong>and</strong> institutional approaches. <strong>The</strong><br />

Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 20(3), 571-610.<br />

Sudarsanam, S. (2003). Creating value from mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions: the challenges:<br />

an integrated <strong>and</strong> international perspective. UK: Prentice Hall International.<br />

Suddaby, R. (2006). From the editors: What grounded theory is not. Academy <strong>of</strong><br />

Management Journal, 49(4), 633–642.<br />

Swift, T. (2001). Trust, reputation <strong>and</strong> corporate accountability to stakeholders.<br />

Business Ethics: A European Review, 10(1), 16-26.<br />

Szulanski, G. (1996). Exploring internal stickiness: Impediments to the transfer <strong>of</strong> best<br />

practice within the firm. Strategic management journal, 27-43.<br />

Szulanski, G. (2003). Sticky knowledge: barriers to knowing in the firm: Sage.<br />

Tanriverdi, H., & Venkatraman, N. (2005). Knowledge relatedness <strong>and</strong> the<br />

performance <strong>of</strong> multibusiness firms. Strategic Management Journal, 26(2), 97-<br />

119.<br />

Taylor, B. (2006). Shell Shock: why do good companies do bad things? Corporate<br />

Governance: An International Review, 14(3), 181-193.<br />

Taylor, M., & Asheim, B. (2001). <strong>The</strong> Concept <strong>of</strong> the Firm in Economic Geography.<br />

Economic Geography, 77(4), 315-328.<br />

Teece, D., Pisano, G., & Shuen, A. (1997). Dynamic Capabilities <strong>and</strong> Strategic<br />

Management. Strategic Management Journal, 18(7), 509-533.<br />

Telser, L. (1980). A <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> Self-Enforcing Agreements. <strong>The</strong> Journal <strong>of</strong> Business,<br />

53(1), 27-44.<br />

Tesch, P. (1980). Die Bestimmungsgründe des Internationalen H<strong>and</strong>elns und der<br />

Direktinvestition. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.<br />

Thomas, T. (2006). Unternehmenszusammenschlüsse in der Energieversorgung: Eine<br />

Analyse der Übernahmewelle der 1990er Jahre in Nordamerika und Europa.<br />

Wiesbaden: Deutscher Universitätsverlag.<br />

Thrift, N., & Olds, K. (1996). Refiguring the economic in economic. Progress in<br />

Human Geography, 20, 311-337.<br />

Tollison, R. (1982). Rent seeking: a survey. Kyklos, 35, 575-602.<br />

Tönnies, F. ([1887] 2001). Community <strong>and</strong> Society (Gemeinschaft und Gesellschaft)<br />

(J. Harris & M. Hollis, Trans.). Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Trochim, W. (1989). Outcome pattern matching <strong>and</strong> program theory. Evaluation <strong>and</strong><br />

Program Planning, 12(4), 355-366.<br />

Tsai, W. (2000). Social capital, strategic relatedness <strong>and</strong> the formation <strong>of</strong><br />

intraorganizational linkages. Strategic Management Journal, 925-939.<br />

Tsai, W., & Ghoshal, S. (1998). Social capital <strong>and</strong> value creation: <strong>The</strong> role <strong>of</strong> intrafirm<br />

networks. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Journal, 41(4), 464-476.<br />

Ugaz, C., & Price, C. (2003). Utility privatization <strong>and</strong> regulation: a fair deal for<br />

consumers? Cheltenham, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing.<br />

Uzzi, B. (1996). <strong>The</strong> sources <strong>and</strong> consequences <strong>of</strong> embeddedness for the economic<br />

performance <strong>of</strong> organizations: <strong>The</strong> network effect. American sociological<br />

review, 61(4), 674-698.


Bibliography<br />

Uzzi, B. (1999). Embeddedness in the making <strong>of</strong> financial capital: How social<br />

relations <strong>and</strong> networks benefit firms seeking financing. American sociological<br />

review, 64, 481-505.<br />

Van de Ven, A. (1992). Suggestions for studying strategy process: A research note.<br />

Strategic management journal, 13(S1), 169-188.<br />

Van de Ven, A. (2004). <strong>The</strong> context-specific nature <strong>of</strong> competence <strong>and</strong> corporate<br />

development. Asia Pacific Journal <strong>of</strong> Management, 21(1), 123-147.<br />

Von Thünen, J. (1826). Der isolierte Staat in Beziehung auf L<strong>and</strong>wirtschaft und<br />

Nationalökonomie, 1. Teil (1 ed.). Hamburg.<br />

Voss, C., Tsikriktsis, N., & Frohlich, M. (2002). Case research in operations<br />

management. International Journal <strong>of</strong> Operations <strong>and</strong> Production<br />

Management, 22(2), 195-219.<br />

Voss, T. (2003). <strong>The</strong> rational choice approach to an analysis <strong>of</strong> intra-<strong>and</strong><br />

interorganizational governance. Research in the Sociology <strong>of</strong> Organizations, 20,<br />

21–46.<br />

Waddock, S., & Graves, S. (1997). <strong>The</strong> Corporate Social Performance-Financial<br />

Performance Link. Strategic Management Journal, 18(4), 303-319.<br />

Walker, G., Kogut, B., & Shan, W. (1997). Social Capital, Structural Holes <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Formation <strong>of</strong> an Industry Network. Organization Science, 8(2), 109-125.<br />

Walker, J., & Ostrom, E. (2007). Trust <strong>and</strong> Reciprocity as foundations for<br />

Cooperation: Individuals, Institutions, <strong>and</strong> Context. Paper presented at the<br />

Capstone Meeting <strong>of</strong> the RSF Trust Initiative, New York.<br />

Ward, W., & Hite, J. (1999). Asset <strong>Fixity</strong>, Asset Specificity <strong>and</strong> Regional Economic<br />

Change: Hypothesis <strong>and</strong> Implications.Unpublished manuscript.<br />

Wartenweiler, J. (2005, 04 August). Die Staumauer der Vernunft. Die Wochenzeitung.<br />

Wathne, K., & Heide, J. (2000). Opportunism in interfirm relationships: forms,<br />

outcomes, <strong>and</strong> solutions. <strong>The</strong> Journal <strong>of</strong> Marketing, 64, 36-51.<br />

WBCSD. (n.d.). Cement production. Retrieved 15 February, 2010, from<br />

http://www.wbcsdcement.org/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=<br />

69&Itemid=140<br />

Weber, M. (1947). <strong>The</strong> <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> Social <strong>and</strong> Economic Organization (Vol. 360). New<br />

York: Free Press.<br />

Weber, M. (1978). Economy <strong>and</strong> Society (Vol. 1). Berkeley.<br />

Weiss, A., Anderson, E., & MacInnis, D. (1999). Reputation Management as a<br />

Motivation for Sales Structure Decisions. <strong>The</strong> Journal <strong>of</strong> Marketing, 63(4), 74-<br />

89.<br />

Weiss, G. (2009, 03 May). Milliardenschwere Energieprojekte blockiert. NZZ am<br />

Sonntag.<br />

Westney, E. (1993). Institutionalization theory <strong>and</strong> the multinational corporation. In S.<br />

Ghoshal & E. Westney (Eds.), Organization theory <strong>and</strong> the multinational<br />

corporation (pp. 53-76). New York: St. Martin's Press.<br />

Whitley, R. (2003). How national are business systems? <strong>The</strong> role <strong>of</strong> different state<br />

types <strong>and</strong> complementary institutions in constructing homogenous systems <strong>of</strong><br />

economic co-ordination <strong>and</strong> control.Unpublished manuscript, Manchester.<br />

Williamson, O. (1975). Markets <strong>and</strong> hierarchies: Analysis <strong>and</strong> Antitrust Implications.<br />

New York, NY: Free Press.<br />

389


390<br />

Bibliography<br />

Williamson, O. (1981). <strong>The</strong> Economics <strong>of</strong> Organization: <strong>The</strong> Transaction Cost<br />

Approach. <strong>The</strong> American Journal <strong>of</strong> Sociology, 87(3), 548-577.<br />

Williamson, O. (1983). Credible commitments: using hostages to support exchange.<br />

<strong>The</strong> American Economic Review, 519-538.<br />

Williamson, O. (1985a). Assessing Contract. Journal <strong>of</strong> Law, Economics, &<br />

Organization, 1(1), 177-208.<br />

Williamson, O. (1985b). <strong>The</strong> Economic Institutions <strong>of</strong> Capitalism. New York: <strong>The</strong><br />

Free Press.<br />

Williamson, O. (1991). Comparative economic organization: <strong>The</strong> analysis <strong>of</strong> discrete<br />

structural alternatives. Administrative science quarterly, 36(2), 269-296.<br />

Williamson, O. (1996). <strong>The</strong> mechanisms <strong>of</strong> governance. New York: Oxford University<br />

Press.<br />

Williamson, O. (2002). <strong>The</strong> Lens <strong>of</strong> Contract: Private Ordering. <strong>The</strong> American<br />

Economic Review, 92(2), 438-443.<br />

Winter, S. (1995). Four Rs <strong>of</strong> Pr<strong>of</strong>itability: Rents, Resources, Routines, <strong>and</strong><br />

Replication. In C. Montgomery (Ed.), Resource-based <strong>and</strong> evolutionary<br />

theories <strong>of</strong> the firm: Towards a synthesis (pp. 147-158). Boston, MA: Kluwer.<br />

Wittmer, A., Fröhlich, P., Weinert, R., & Axhausen, K. (2008). Luftfahrt im<br />

Spannungsfeld von Ökonomie, Ökologie und Gesellschaft: Untersuchungen der<br />

Luftfahrtentwicklung unter Einbezug von Reisezeitersparnissen und<br />

Emissionen am Beispiel des Interkontinentalflughafens Zürich (pp. 1-67). St.<br />

Gallen: Center for Aviation Competence, University <strong>of</strong> St. Gallen.<br />

Wood, D. (1991). Corporate Social Performance Revisited. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong><br />

Management Review, 16(4), 691-718.<br />

Xu, D., & Shenkar, O. (2002). Institutional distance <strong>and</strong> the multinational enterprise.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Review, 27(4), 608-618.<br />

Yeung, H. (2000). Organizing 'the firm' in industrial geography I: Networks,<br />

institutions <strong>and</strong> regional development. Progress in Human Geography, 24(2),<br />

301-315.<br />

Yeung, H. (2000, 4-7 January). Practicing new economic geographies? Some<br />

methodological considerations. Paper presented at the RGS-IBG Annual<br />

Conference, Brighton.<br />

Yeung, H. (2001). Does economics matter for/in economic geography? Antipode,<br />

33(2), 168-175.<br />

Yeung, H. (2003). Practicing new economic geographies: a methodological<br />

examination. Annals <strong>of</strong> the Association <strong>of</strong> American Geographers, 93(2), 442-<br />

462.<br />

Yeung, H., & Lin, G. (2003). <strong>The</strong>orizing economic geographies <strong>of</strong> Asia. Economic<br />

Geography, 79(2), 107-128.<br />

Yin, R. (1994). Case study research: design <strong>and</strong> methods (2nd ed.). Thous<strong>and</strong> Oaks,<br />

CA: Sage Publications.<br />

Zademach, H. (2002). ‘<strong>The</strong> Firm in Economic Geography’–zu einer integrierten<br />

Konzeption der Unternehmung. Munich: Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität<br />

München, Fakultät für Betriebswirtschaft.<br />

Zaheer, A., McEvily, B., & Perrone, V. (1998). Does Trust Matter? Exploring the<br />

<strong>Effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> Interorganizational <strong>and</strong> Interpersonal Trust on Performance.<br />

Organization Science, 9(2), 141-159.


Bibliography<br />

Zaheer, S. (1995). Overcoming the Liability <strong>of</strong> Foreignness. <strong>The</strong> Academy <strong>of</strong><br />

Management Journal, 38(2), 341-363.<br />

Zöller, K. (2004). Stakeholder-Dialoge zur Sicherung des neuen St<strong>and</strong>ortfaktors<br />

„Akzeptanz“ bei deutschen und amerikanischen Chemieunternehmen. Eine<br />

wirtschaftsgeographische Untersuchung. Universität Köln, Köln.<br />

Zucker, L. (1977). <strong>The</strong> Role <strong>of</strong> Institutionalization in Cultural Persistence. American<br />

Sociological Review, 42(5), 726-743.<br />

Zucker, L. (1987). Institutional <strong>The</strong>ories <strong>of</strong> Organization. Annual Review <strong>of</strong> Sociology,<br />

13, 443-464.<br />

Zukin, S., & DiMaggio, P. (1990). Structures <strong>of</strong> Capital: <strong>The</strong> Social Organization <strong>of</strong><br />

the Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.<br />

391


392<br />

Curriculum Vitae Annette Karoline Ulmer<br />

Date <strong>and</strong> place <strong>of</strong> birth<br />

February 6, 1976 in St. Gallen, Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

Education<br />

Curriculum Vitae<br />

2006 – 2010 University <strong>of</strong> St. Gallen (CH), Institute for Systemic<br />

Management <strong>and</strong> Public Governance, doctoral thesis at the<br />

chair <strong>of</strong> Pr<strong>of</strong>. Dr. Thomas Bieger<br />

1995-2000 University <strong>of</strong> St. Gallen (CH), undergraduate <strong>and</strong> graduate<br />

studies <strong>of</strong> business administration; exchange semesters at<br />

the University <strong>of</strong> Geneva (HEC; CH) <strong>and</strong> University <strong>of</strong><br />

Western Ontario (CA)<br />

1988-1995 High School, Bundesgymnasium Dornbirn (AT)<br />

Work experience<br />

2010 – today Flughafen Zürich AG, Vice President International<br />

Business Development<br />

2005 – 2009 Flughafen Zürich AG, Senior Project Manager, various<br />

functions in international business development<br />

2003 – 2005 Lindt & Spruengli (Switzerl<strong>and</strong>), Key Account Manager;<br />

<strong>and</strong> Lindt & Spruengli (North East), Br<strong>and</strong> Manager<br />

2001 – 2002 Swiss Air Lines, Project Manager<br />

2000 – 2001 Swissair, Management Traineeship

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!