07.06.2013 Views

Changes in Mutual Fund Flows and Managerial Incentives

Changes in Mutual Fund Flows and Managerial Incentives

Changes in Mutual Fund Flows and Managerial Incentives

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Changes</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> <strong>Flows</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Managerial</strong> <strong>Incentives</strong><br />

M<strong>in</strong> S. Kim ∗<br />

University of New South Wales<br />

December 1, 2010<br />

Abstract<br />

I show that the shape of the relationship between mutual fund flows <strong>and</strong> past performance<br />

varies over time. In particular, flows become less sensitive to high performance follow<strong>in</strong>g periods<br />

of volatile markets <strong>and</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g periods of less dispersion <strong>in</strong> performance across funds. As a<br />

result, dur<strong>in</strong>g the 2000s, when both effects are present, the flow-performance relationship is not<br />

convex. Moreover, I show that underperform<strong>in</strong>g managers engage <strong>in</strong> less risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g towards<br />

the end of the year when markets are volatile <strong>and</strong> performance is less dispersed across funds.<br />

These results are consistent with the view that <strong>in</strong>vestors’flows respond more to performance<br />

when it is more <strong>in</strong>formative <strong>and</strong> that fund managers anticipate this variable flow response.<br />

JEL Classification Codes: C14, G10, G20, G23<br />

Keywords: mutual funds, flow-performance relationship, risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g<br />

∗ School of Bank<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> F<strong>in</strong>ance, Australian School of Bus<strong>in</strong>ess, University of New South Wales, email:<br />

m<strong>in</strong>.kim@unsw.edu.au. I thank Stephen Brown, Daniel Carvalho, George Cashman (discussant), Christopher Clifford<br />

(discussant), Harry DeAngelo, Wayne Ferson, Christopher Jones, Aneel Keswani (discussant), Diana Knyazeva, John<br />

Long, Tim Loughran, Pedro Matos, Rosa Liliana Matzk<strong>in</strong>, Kev<strong>in</strong> Murphy, Oguzhan Ozbas, Raghavendra Rau, Anto<strong>in</strong>ette<br />

Schoar, Clemens Sialm, David Solomon, Kumar Venkataraman, Jerold Warner, Mark Westerfield, William<br />

Zame, <strong>and</strong> participants at the EFA aanula meet<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> Frankfurt, the FIRS conference <strong>in</strong> Florence, the FMA annual<br />

meet<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> Reno <strong>and</strong> at the f<strong>in</strong>ance sem<strong>in</strong>ars at Drexel University, Hong Kong University of Science <strong>and</strong> Technology,<br />

INSEAD, National University of S<strong>in</strong>gapore, Rutgers University, University of New South Wales, University of Notre<br />

Dame, University of Rochester, <strong>and</strong> University of Southern California for their helpful comments. I am especially<br />

grateful to my advisor Wayne Ferson, Christopher Jones, Mark Westerfield, <strong>and</strong> William Zame for valuable discussions<br />

<strong>and</strong> suggestions. All errors are my own.


An important issue <strong>in</strong> the agency literature is the <strong>in</strong>centive effects of compensation structures<br />

on agents’real behavior. In the mutual fund <strong>in</strong>dustry, given that fees are proportional to assets<br />

under management, the relationship between money flows <strong>and</strong> past performance can <strong>in</strong>duce implicit<br />

performance compensation. Brown, Harlow, <strong>and</strong> Starks (1996) <strong>and</strong> Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison (1997)<br />

argue that convexity <strong>in</strong> the relationship provides managers who are beh<strong>in</strong>d the markets (or their<br />

peers) with <strong>in</strong>centives to take more risk towards the end of the year. These actions are undertaken<br />

<strong>in</strong> an attempt to improve performance <strong>and</strong> thereby <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong>flows <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g year. Given<br />

that the implicit payoff looks like a call option, underperform<strong>in</strong>g managers may engage <strong>in</strong> such<br />

risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g even at the expense of <strong>in</strong>vestors’<strong>in</strong>terests. 1<br />

This paper exam<strong>in</strong>es whether managers respond to the <strong>in</strong>centives provided by this implicit<br />

compensation scheme. To this end, I look at how their risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g varies accord<strong>in</strong>g to the shape<br />

of the relationship between net flows <strong>and</strong> past performance (e.g., benchmark-adjusted returns <strong>in</strong><br />

the prior year). I show that contrary to the common view <strong>in</strong> the literature that the relationship is<br />

convex, its shape depends on condition<strong>in</strong>g variables, particularly market volatility <strong>and</strong> performance<br />

dispersion across funds. I then study manager’s risk shift<strong>in</strong>g as it relates to time variation <strong>in</strong> the<br />

shape of the flow-performance relationship.<br />

I first show that the flow-performance relationship varies over time. I f<strong>in</strong>d that the shape<br />

of the relationship is less convex when stock markets are volatile <strong>and</strong> when performance is less<br />

dispersed across funds. In particular, the sensitivity of flows to high perform<strong>in</strong>g funds decreases<br />

follow<strong>in</strong>g periods of high-volatility markets <strong>and</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g periods of low performance dispersion.<br />

Controll<strong>in</strong>g for market volatility <strong>and</strong> performance dispersion, we cannot reject the hypothesis that<br />

1 Earlier studies that document the convex flow-performance relationship <strong>in</strong>clude Ippolito (1992), Goetzmann <strong>and</strong><br />

Peles (1996), Gruber (1996), Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison (1997), <strong>and</strong> Sirri <strong>and</strong> Tufano (1998). In the models of Starks<br />

(1987) <strong>and</strong> Panageas <strong>and</strong> Westerfield (2009), option-like <strong>in</strong>centive fees can lead to managers’risk-seek<strong>in</strong>g behavior.<br />

Koski <strong>and</strong> Pontiff (1999) argue that fund managers use derivatives to manage unexpected cash flows rather than to<br />

take more risk <strong>in</strong> an attempt to <strong>in</strong>crease expected flows. Busse (2001) <strong>and</strong> Elton et. al. (2009) f<strong>in</strong>d different results<br />

than those <strong>in</strong> Brown, Harlow, <strong>and</strong> Starks, when us<strong>in</strong>g daily return <strong>and</strong> monthly hold<strong>in</strong>g data respectively.<br />

1


flows are l<strong>in</strong>early related to performance. Such variations lead to an alteration <strong>in</strong> the shape of<br />

the flow-performance relationship <strong>in</strong> the 2000s. Consistent with earlier studies, it is convex from<br />

1983 to 1999, but it is not convex dur<strong>in</strong>g the highly volatile market conditions of the early 2000s.<br />

In addition, managers’ risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g behaviors tend to differ accord<strong>in</strong>g to these two condition<strong>in</strong>g<br />

variables: performance dispersion <strong>and</strong> market volatility. When the expected shape of the flow-<br />

performance relationship conditional on those variables is not convex (i.e., when performance is<br />

less dispersed <strong>and</strong> when markets are more volatile), underperformers do not engage <strong>in</strong> risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

As a result, <strong>in</strong> the 2000s, managers perform<strong>in</strong>g worse than the markets tend to reduce risk- shift<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

My results are consistent with the view that <strong>in</strong>vestors’flows respond more to performance when it<br />

is more <strong>in</strong>formative <strong>and</strong> that fund managers anticipate this variable flow response.<br />

Figure I. Flow-performance relationship <strong>and</strong> 90% confidence <strong>in</strong>terval<br />

The y-axes represent expected annual net flows <strong>in</strong>to <strong>and</strong> out of non<strong>in</strong>dex funds from 1983 to 1999<br />

(before 2000) <strong>and</strong> from 2000 to 2008 (after 2000). Performance is annual returns m<strong>in</strong>us the CRSP value<br />

weighted <strong>in</strong>dex (CRSP VW). The expected annual net flows are estimated us<strong>in</strong>g kernel regressions suggested<br />

by Rob<strong>in</strong>son (1988) after controll<strong>in</strong>g for contemporaneous performance, the second lag of performance, age,<br />

size, expense ratio, volatility, <strong>and</strong> lagged flow of funds, <strong>in</strong>dustry flow, <strong>and</strong> style flow. See Table I for the<br />

variable description. <strong>Fund</strong>s are aggregated across share classes, exclud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutional share classes. The<br />

total number of funds is 2,264 over 1983 to 2008 <strong>and</strong> the numbers of observations are 6,771 <strong>and</strong> 10,908 before<br />

2000 <strong>and</strong> after 2000 respectively.<br />

expected annual net flows<br />

0.5<br />

0.4<br />

0.3<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

0<br />

­0.1<br />

­0.2<br />

before 2000<br />

after 2000<br />

­0.25 ­0.2 ­0.15 ­0.1 ­0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25<br />

lagged return over the market value­weighted <strong>in</strong>dex<br />

2


I estimate the relationship between fund flows <strong>and</strong> excess returns over the markets from 1983<br />

to 1999 <strong>and</strong> from 2000 to 2008 respectively, us<strong>in</strong>g kernel regression (Figure I). After controll<strong>in</strong>g for<br />

the effects of fund characteristics <strong>and</strong> money flows to the mutual fund <strong>in</strong>dustry as a whole, I f<strong>in</strong>d<br />

substantial decreases <strong>in</strong> convexity <strong>in</strong> the recent period. In particular, the marg<strong>in</strong>al flow to high<br />

perform<strong>in</strong>g funds does not <strong>in</strong>crease with performance. As a consequence, a fund outperform<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

market value-weighted <strong>in</strong>dex by 20% attracted annual net flows of 30% prior to 2000 on average<br />

but only 10% <strong>in</strong> the subsequent decade. 2 Given the average fund sizes of $1 billion <strong>and</strong> $1.4 billion<br />

dur<strong>in</strong>g those periods, respectively, this type of fund had annual net <strong>in</strong>flows of $300 million prior<br />

to 2000 on average, but only $140 million after that. Ord<strong>in</strong>ary least square (OLS) regressions also<br />

confirm these changes. The coeffi cient on squared performance decreases from 0.6 to -0.3 after<br />

2000, which suggests a change from a convex to a concave relationship (when the relationship is<br />

<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g, the predom<strong>in</strong>ant difference <strong>in</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>al flow for high performance can be captured by<br />

convexity or concavity). I also f<strong>in</strong>d similar decreases <strong>in</strong> convexity us<strong>in</strong>g rank<strong>in</strong>g as performance<br />

measure. 3<br />

I show that time-variation <strong>in</strong> the flow-performance sensitivity (expected marg<strong>in</strong>al flow) con-<br />

tributes to the concave shape <strong>in</strong> the 2000s. Throughout the period from 1983 to 2008, the flow-<br />

performance relationship is concave follow<strong>in</strong>g periods of highly volatile markets, whereas it is convex<br />

follow<strong>in</strong>g periods of low-volatility markets. I also f<strong>in</strong>d that the shape is more convex when per-<br />

formance is more dispersed across funds (after controll<strong>in</strong>g market volatility). For example, 10% of<br />

performance dispersion reduces the concavity <strong>in</strong> highly volatile markets by around half.<br />

2 The changes <strong>in</strong> the flow-performance relationship are predom<strong>in</strong>ant for high performance, not for low performance.<br />

This can be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs that the (net) flow-performance relationship arises from the responses of <strong>in</strong>flows<br />

to past performance <strong>and</strong> outflows are unrelated to past performance (see Bergstesser <strong>and</strong> Poterba (2002), O’Neal<br />

(2004), Johnson (2007), <strong>and</strong> Ivkovic <strong>and</strong> Weisbenner (2009)).<br />

3 Us<strong>in</strong>g rank<strong>in</strong>g of raw returns as a performance measure, I also f<strong>in</strong>d a substantial decrease <strong>in</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>al flow to<br />

top-ranked funds <strong>in</strong> the post-2000 period. Performance dispersion <strong>in</strong>creases convexity of the relationship between<br />

net flows <strong>and</strong> performance rank<strong>in</strong>g, but market volatility appears statistically <strong>in</strong>significant for the relationship. See<br />

Section III.C for the details.<br />

3


These results are consistent with the predictions <strong>in</strong> Berk <strong>and</strong> Green (2004) <strong>and</strong> Kim (2010)<br />

that the marg<strong>in</strong>al flow to high-perform<strong>in</strong>g funds is low when performance is less attributable to<br />

skills. In both models, <strong>in</strong>vestors use past performance– represented as skills plus noise– as an<br />

<strong>in</strong>ference of managers’abilities (<strong>and</strong> efforts). When performance reflects more luck relative to skill,<br />

the sensitivity of flows to superior performance is low. The contribution of skills to performance<br />

<strong>in</strong>creases with cross-sectional variation <strong>in</strong> skills but decreases with variation <strong>in</strong> noise. As a result,<br />

when skills are less heterogeneous across managers <strong>and</strong> when performance appears noisier, <strong>in</strong>vestors<br />

become less responsive to high performance. 4<br />

<strong>Changes</strong> <strong>in</strong> risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g behavior are consistent with the view that managers respond to the<br />

<strong>in</strong>centives provided by the implicit performance compensation. Given the changes <strong>in</strong> the shape of<br />

the flow-performance relationship, I exam<strong>in</strong>e variations <strong>in</strong> the relationship between performance<br />

<strong>and</strong> risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g. Low-perform<strong>in</strong>g funds typically take more risk <strong>in</strong> the fourth quarter, but this<br />

risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g is significantly reduced after 2000, decreas<strong>in</strong>g by about 70%. The same variables<br />

that determ<strong>in</strong>e the shape of the flow-performance relationship also expla<strong>in</strong> these changes. After<br />

condition<strong>in</strong>g the relationship between performance <strong>and</strong> risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g, I f<strong>in</strong>d that managers who are<br />

beh<strong>in</strong>d the markets tend to <strong>in</strong>crease risk <strong>in</strong> the fourth quarter when performance <strong>in</strong> the middle of<br />

the year is more dispersed across funds. In periods when performance dispersion is low, it is the<br />

high-perform<strong>in</strong>g managers who engage <strong>in</strong> such risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g. I also show that low-perform<strong>in</strong>g funds<br />

tend to take more systematic risk <strong>in</strong> the rest of the year when market volatility up to the third<br />

quarter is low.<br />

The ma<strong>in</strong> contribution of the paper is to propose a conditional relationship between flows<br />

4 In the model presented <strong>in</strong> Kim (2010), there is no <strong>in</strong>tr<strong>in</strong>sic shape <strong>in</strong> the flow-performance relationship. Rather, <strong>in</strong><br />

equilibrium, <strong>in</strong>centive fees depend on the likelihood that the manager has high skills <strong>and</strong> actively manages the fund<br />

relative to the likelihood that she follows a passive <strong>in</strong>dex strategy. Thus, the shape can be convex, l<strong>in</strong>ear or concave.<br />

Del Guercio <strong>and</strong> Tkac (2002) f<strong>in</strong>d a symmetric relationship for pension funds, <strong>and</strong> Kaplan <strong>and</strong> Schoar (2005) f<strong>in</strong>d a<br />

concave relationship for private equity funds.<br />

4


<strong>and</strong> performance 5 <strong>and</strong> to document changes <strong>in</strong> managers’risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g behavior accord<strong>in</strong>g to the<br />

expected shape of the relationship. In particular, I show that flows are less responsive to high<br />

performance when markets are volatile <strong>and</strong> when performance is less dispersed across funds <strong>in</strong> the<br />

prior period. These variations lead to nonconvexity <strong>in</strong> the relationship <strong>in</strong> the 2000s. On the other<br />

h<strong>and</strong>, Huang, Wei, <strong>and</strong> Yan (2005) <strong>and</strong> Sigurdsson (2005) f<strong>in</strong>d that <strong>in</strong> the 1990s, flows become<br />

more sensitive for middle (<strong>and</strong> low) performance, lead<strong>in</strong>g to a more l<strong>in</strong>ear relationship between<br />

flows <strong>and</strong> performance, than <strong>in</strong> the 1980s.<br />

In addition, this paper makes several contributions. First, my f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs provide an explanation<br />

for the recent growth <strong>in</strong> passive management <strong>in</strong> the mutual fund <strong>in</strong>dustry, such as closet-<strong>in</strong>dex<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Managers face fewer <strong>in</strong>centives to engage <strong>in</strong> active management because of lower marg<strong>in</strong>al flow<br />

to high-perform<strong>in</strong>g funds. As suggested <strong>in</strong> Kim (2010), managers track market <strong>in</strong>dexes when<br />

performance-based compensation for active funds is low. Second, while <strong>in</strong>vestors are less attracted<br />

to superior performance <strong>in</strong> the 2000s, fund flows are negatively related to expense ratios. I f<strong>in</strong>d<br />

that funds with high expense ratios had more <strong>in</strong>flows before 2000 (see also Barber, Odean, Zheng<br />

(2005) <strong>and</strong> Huang, Wei, <strong>and</strong> Yan (2005)). Yet, after 2000, my results show that a 1% <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong><br />

the ratios led to a 3-5% decrease <strong>in</strong> net flows. This is consistent with recent anecdotal evidence that<br />

past performance is no longer the most important factor, whereas fees have become critical when<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestors choose mutual funds. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to a survey by the Investment Company Institute <strong>in</strong><br />

2006, more <strong>in</strong>vestors consider fees rather than past performance (see “Investors Flock to Low-Cost<br />

<strong>Fund</strong>s,”J. Clements, 2007, The Wall Street Journal). As discussed <strong>in</strong> Appendix, the negative effect<br />

of expense ratios after 2000 seems to be associated with a decrease <strong>in</strong> 12b-1 fees, most of which are<br />

used to compensate f<strong>in</strong>ancial advisers. F<strong>in</strong>ally, my results are consistent with <strong>in</strong>vestors attempt<strong>in</strong>g<br />

to dist<strong>in</strong>guish skills associated with active management from a passive <strong>in</strong>dex strategy. I f<strong>in</strong>d that the<br />

5 Olivier <strong>and</strong> Tay (2009) <strong>and</strong> Wang (2009) show that contemporaneous GDP growth affects the flow-performance<br />

relationship. My paper uses lagged variables to form a conditional expectation about the shape of the relationship.<br />

5


flow-performance relationship is <strong>in</strong>significant for <strong>in</strong>dex funds <strong>in</strong> most cases (see also Elton, Gruber,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Busse (2004)). Nonetheless, <strong>in</strong>dex fund flows seem to <strong>in</strong>crease with performance compared to<br />

the funds with the same value <strong>and</strong> size characteristics. Given that outperform<strong>in</strong>g those peer funds<br />

requires more than passive management, the results are consistent with the view that <strong>in</strong>vestors chase<br />

good performance because they perceive that it represents skills (e.g., Gruber (1996) <strong>and</strong> Zheng<br />

(1999)). Also, the changes <strong>in</strong> the flow-performance relationship accord<strong>in</strong>g to market volatility <strong>and</strong><br />

performance dispersion that I document seem less supportive of a story where <strong>in</strong>vestors irrationally<br />

chase recent w<strong>in</strong>ner funds (e.g., Sapp <strong>and</strong> Tiwari (2004)). 6<br />

Section I <strong>and</strong> II discuss methodologies <strong>and</strong> results for changes <strong>in</strong> the flow-performance relation-<br />

ship <strong>and</strong> changes <strong>in</strong> managers’risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g respectively. I present the results of robustness check<br />

<strong>in</strong> Section III <strong>and</strong> conclude <strong>in</strong> Section IV.<br />

I. Flow-performance relationship<br />

A. Data <strong>and</strong> variable description<br />

I obta<strong>in</strong> market <strong>in</strong>dexes <strong>and</strong> mutual fund data from Morn<strong>in</strong>gstar, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g returns, total net<br />

assets (TNA), 9 style categories (value <strong>and</strong> size), <strong>in</strong>dex fund flags, <strong>and</strong> funds’benchmark <strong>in</strong>dexes<br />

as disclosed <strong>in</strong> fund prospectuses. I aggregate across share classes based on their TNA. 7 Market<br />

returns are proxied by the Center for Research <strong>in</strong> Security Prices value-weighted (CRSP VW) <strong>in</strong>dex.<br />

My sample covers all U.S. equity mutual funds, exclud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex funds (accord<strong>in</strong>g to fund<br />

prospectuses), sector funds, specialized funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds, from 1983 to 2008 annually<br />

(data starts <strong>in</strong> 1980 to obta<strong>in</strong> lagged variables). To compare my results with Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison<br />

6 I also f<strong>in</strong>d that <strong>in</strong> the areas where hedge funds are concentrated (New York <strong>and</strong> Boston), marg<strong>in</strong>al flow to high<br />

perform<strong>in</strong>g funds decreases more compared to other areas after 2000. The market share of the funds (whose managers<br />

are) <strong>in</strong> those areas decreases from 50% <strong>in</strong> 1999 to 30% <strong>in</strong> 2008. These results can support a view that flows are less<br />

sensitive to high-performance because skilled managers leave the <strong>in</strong>dustry (e.g., a bra<strong>in</strong> dra<strong>in</strong> to hedge funds; see<br />

Kostovetsky (2007) <strong>and</strong> Massa, Reuter <strong>and</strong> Zitzewitz (2009)).<br />

7 I obta<strong>in</strong>ed similar results us<strong>in</strong>g the CRSP data. Us<strong>in</strong>g only Morn<strong>in</strong>gstar <strong>in</strong>creases the sample size (no crossidentification<br />

between two data sets) <strong>and</strong> better aggregates across share classes.<br />

6


(1997), I follow their sampl<strong>in</strong>g criteria. I remove small funds (assets less than $10 million) <strong>and</strong><br />

young funds (less than 3 years old) as of the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the period over which fund flows are<br />

measured. 8 I also exclude the funds that are closed to new or all <strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong> their clos<strong>in</strong>g years<br />

<strong>and</strong> afterwards (See Bris et. al. (2007) for a detailed discussion about fund closures), <strong>in</strong>stitutional<br />

share classes, funds that acquire other funds <strong>in</strong> their merger years, <strong>and</strong> the funds that are liquidated<br />

with<strong>in</strong> 6 months before the date that fund flows are measured.<br />

<strong>Fund</strong> flows are measured annually at the end of December <strong>and</strong> lagged performance over the<br />

preced<strong>in</strong>g calendar year. I def<strong>in</strong>e fund flows as a percentage change <strong>in</strong> TNA, net of capital ga<strong>in</strong>s<br />

<strong>and</strong> dividends from <strong>in</strong>vestments. I measure net flows of a fund i at year t by<br />

net flowi,t = T NAi,t − T NAi,t−12<br />

T NAi,t−12<br />

where ri,t is the fund’s return over the period from t − 1 to t. 9<br />

− ri,t<br />

Follow<strong>in</strong>g Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison (1997), I measure performance as excess returns over CRSP<br />

VW returns. S<strong>in</strong>ce I focus on <strong>in</strong>vestors’reactions to performance, I also use simple performance<br />

measures that may be readily available to <strong>in</strong>vestors. In particular, relative returns compared to<br />

benchmark <strong>in</strong>dexes or to the S&P500 <strong>in</strong>dex are available on fund companies’websites or f<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

websites such as Yahoo! F<strong>in</strong>ance. Del Guercio <strong>and</strong> Tkac (2002) show that excess returns over market<br />

<strong>in</strong>dexes, such as the S&P500 <strong>in</strong>dex, are important determ<strong>in</strong>ants of mutual fund flows. They also<br />

provide evidence that mutual fund flows are related to factor-adjusted performance measures as the<br />

sophisticated measures are correlated with readily available measures. When a fund’s benchmark<br />

<strong>in</strong>dex is miss<strong>in</strong>g, I use the most frequently used benchmark by other funds with the same styles<br />

8 Young funds may go through an <strong>in</strong>cubation process. Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison (1997) <strong>in</strong>clude funds between two <strong>and</strong><br />

three years old. I exclude them s<strong>in</strong>ce I also use lagged flows as a control variable. Results are similar if I <strong>in</strong>clude<br />

them.<br />

9 To avoid effects due to measurement errors or extreme observations, I w<strong>in</strong>sorize fund flows at 1% <strong>and</strong> 99% levels<br />

follow<strong>in</strong>g Barber, Odean <strong>and</strong> Zhang (2005). My results do not depend on those outliers.<br />

(1)<br />

7


(Sirri <strong>and</strong> Tufano (1998) use relative returns compared to the funds with the same <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

objectives). F<strong>in</strong>ally, I also compute average returns on equity funds <strong>in</strong> the same style categories<br />

(peer funds), which I call style returns. Relative returns compared to style returns is likely to be<br />

important if <strong>in</strong>vestors select funds based on value <strong>and</strong> size characteristics <strong>and</strong> make comparisons<br />

among funds with<strong>in</strong> the same style category. To summarize, I use four performance measures<br />

depend<strong>in</strong>g on benchmark returns: CRSP VW, S&P500 <strong>in</strong>dex, the fund’s benchmark <strong>in</strong>dex, <strong>and</strong><br />

style returns.<br />

Other variables used <strong>in</strong> the regressions <strong>in</strong>clude fund size, age, expense ratios <strong>and</strong> volatility.<br />

Many studies f<strong>in</strong>d that a small fund <strong>and</strong> a young fund grow faster (e.g., Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison<br />

(1997), Sirri <strong>and</strong> Tufano (1998), Del Guercio <strong>and</strong> Tkac (2002), <strong>and</strong> Barber, Odean <strong>and</strong> Zhang<br />

(2005)). I measure size as the natural logarithm of ratio of a fund’s TNA to the average TNA of all<br />

equity funds <strong>in</strong> the sample at the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of each year (us<strong>in</strong>g the level could make the variable<br />

nonstationary). I use log age, which is the natural logarithm of the number of months s<strong>in</strong>ce the<br />

<strong>in</strong>ception dates. I also <strong>in</strong>clude expense ratios <strong>in</strong> the regression. Expense ratios do not <strong>in</strong>clude load<br />

fees (Morn<strong>in</strong>gstar does not provide historical load fees; us<strong>in</strong>g the CRSP data, I add one-seventh of<br />

load fees, as Sirri <strong>and</strong> Tufano (1998) suggest, <strong>and</strong> obta<strong>in</strong> similar results). Some studies f<strong>in</strong>d that<br />

fund flows are negatively related to volatility of past returns. I measure volatility as the st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

deviation of monthly returns over the prior two years (see Barber, Odean <strong>and</strong> Zheng (2005)).<br />

I also control for net flows to the <strong>in</strong>dustry (all equity mutual funds <strong>in</strong> the CRSP database)<br />

as a whole s<strong>in</strong>ce they could <strong>in</strong>fluence flows to <strong>in</strong>dividual funds. Industry flow can also h<strong>and</strong>le<br />

fixed time effects if any. Cooper, Gulen, <strong>and</strong> Rau (2005) f<strong>in</strong>d that <strong>in</strong>vestors chase styles <strong>and</strong> funds<br />

could attract more <strong>in</strong>flows after chang<strong>in</strong>g their names to reflect popular style characteristics– even<br />

without actual changes <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment styles– over 1994 to 2001. Thus, I also <strong>in</strong>clude style flows (net<br />

flows to funds with specific size <strong>and</strong> value characteristics accord<strong>in</strong>g to the Morn<strong>in</strong>gstar categories)<br />

8


<strong>in</strong> the regressions. I add contemporaneous performance, <strong>and</strong> the second lag of performance to<br />

exam<strong>in</strong>e whether <strong>in</strong>vestors consider less recent performance. To control for fund fixed effects, I use<br />

lagged flows.<br />

My sample <strong>in</strong>cludes 17,679 observations (fund <strong>and</strong> year) for 2,264 funds from 1983 to 2008.<br />

They account for 83% of net assets of non<strong>in</strong>dex funds on average. I conduct a separate analysis<br />

before <strong>and</strong> after 2000, around which the markets <strong>and</strong> the money management <strong>in</strong>dustries seem to<br />

have changed. In early 2000s, the dot-com bubble burst <strong>and</strong> markets were highly volatile. Also,<br />

hedge funds experienced sharp growth. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Hennesse Group LLC, total net assets of<br />

hedge funds <strong>in</strong>creased by 50%, from $221 billion <strong>in</strong> January 1999 to $324 billion <strong>in</strong> January 2000.<br />

From 1998 to 1999, the growth rate was only 6%. The observations are 6,771 <strong>and</strong> 10,908 for the<br />

pre-2000 <strong>and</strong> the post-2000 periods respectively. 10<br />

Table I presents descriptive statistics. Over 1983 to 2008, non<strong>in</strong>dex funds have annual <strong>in</strong>flows<br />

of around 10% on average. Before 2000, the average fund flows are 13%, which decrease to 9%<br />

after 2000. Yet, the decrease is not statistically significant (the t-statistics for the equal means are<br />

adjusted for correlations among funds <strong>and</strong> across years). The average total net assets are about<br />

$1 billion before 2000 <strong>and</strong> grow to $1.4 billion after 2000. Due to the <strong>in</strong>troduction of new funds <strong>in</strong><br />

recent years, the average fund is younger after 2000. The average expense ratios are slightly higher<br />

by 0.05% after 2000. The st<strong>and</strong>ard deviations of monthly returns are similar <strong>in</strong> the subperiods,<br />

around 4.3%. Industry flows <strong>and</strong> style flows are fewer <strong>in</strong> the 2000s. The mutual fund <strong>in</strong>dustry had<br />

net <strong>in</strong>flows of 9% over 1983 to 1999, which decreased to 4%, after 2000 (the difference is significant).<br />

The average net flows to styles are around 10% before 1999 but only 4.7% after 2000.<br />

The sample composition of funds does not have dramatic changes <strong>in</strong> age, size <strong>and</strong> style around<br />

2000 as shown <strong>in</strong> Figure II. I def<strong>in</strong>e young funds <strong>and</strong> small funds as those funds below the median<br />

10 There is also a dramatic change <strong>in</strong> the time-series of the flow-performance relationship around 2000 (Section I.E<br />

<strong>and</strong> Figure 5 (a)). Us<strong>in</strong>g the year 1999 or 2001, I obta<strong>in</strong>ed similar results.<br />

9


age (10 years) <strong>and</strong> size ($0.3 billion) respectively. Panel (A) illustrates that the proportion of large<br />

funds <strong>in</strong>creased dramatically <strong>in</strong> the 1990s. The proportion of young <strong>and</strong> old funds has been stable<br />

s<strong>in</strong>ce early 1990s (Panel (B)). Moreover, the composition of fund styles is also similar throughout<br />

the years.<br />

B. Kernel regression methodology<br />

I use the semi-nonparametric estimation suggested by Rob<strong>in</strong>son (1988). Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison<br />

(1997) use this procedure for the flow-performance relationship but also exam<strong>in</strong>e the sensitivity<br />

differences across fund age groups. They show that flows to old funds (5 years old or more) are<br />

less sensitive to performance. Yet, the differences do not appear statistically significant. Thus, I<br />

estimate the flow-performance relationship for funds of any age, controll<strong>in</strong>g age effects by an age<br />

variable <strong>in</strong> the regressions. I use a panel of funds <strong>and</strong> year <strong>and</strong> estimate<br />

net flowi,t = g(performancei,t−1) + β 3performancei,t + β 4performancei,t−2 + β 5age i,t−1<br />

+β 6size i,t−1 + β 7expensei,t−1 + β 8volatilityi,t−1 + β 9<strong>in</strong>dustryi,t<br />

+β 10stylei,t + β 11net flowi,t−1 + εi,t, (2)<br />

where the variables are described <strong>in</strong> the preced<strong>in</strong>g section. The error term is orthogonal to perfor-<br />

mance as E[εi,t|performancei,t−1] = 0. I estimate the function g(performancei,t−1) us<strong>in</strong>g kernel<br />

regressions. I choose optimal b<strong>and</strong>widths by the cross-validation method, which improves effi ciency<br />

despite its computational costs (see Appendix). Previous studies do not use the cross-validation<br />

method (e.g., Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison (1997) <strong>and</strong> Sensoy (2009)).<br />

As Rob<strong>in</strong>son (1988) proves, we can obta<strong>in</strong> √ n-consistent <strong>and</strong> unbiased estimates for β 3 to β 11<br />

<strong>in</strong> the Equation (2) by the follow<strong>in</strong>g steps: (a) Run each kernel regression of net flows <strong>and</strong> the<br />

10


control variables aga<strong>in</strong>st lagged performance to obta<strong>in</strong> their expected values conditional on lagged<br />

performance; (b) Run OLS regressions of residual net flows on the residual control variables, def<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

as actual values m<strong>in</strong>us expected values obta<strong>in</strong>ed from (a), to estimate β 3 to β 11 (Frisch-Waugh-<br />

Lovell theorem). Us<strong>in</strong>g the estimates β 3 to β 11, I can obta<strong>in</strong> net flow ∗ i,t by<br />

net flow ∗ i,t = net flowi,t − ( β 3performancei,t + β 4performancei,t−2 + β 5age i,t−1<br />

+ β 6size i,t−1 + β 7expensei,t−1 + β 8volatilityi,t−1 + β 9<strong>in</strong>dustryi,t<br />

+ β 10stylei,t + β 11net flowi,t−1). (3)<br />

To estimate g(·), I run kernel regressions of net flow ∗ i,t aga<strong>in</strong>st performancei,t−1. This func-<br />

tion has the <strong>in</strong>terpretation, E[net flow ∗ i,t |performancei,t−1] = g(performancei,t−1). In words, I<br />

estimate the flow-performance relationship as expected fund flows conditional on past performance,<br />

controll<strong>in</strong>g other factors, such as <strong>in</strong>dustry growth, size, <strong>and</strong> age. One limitation of this method is<br />

its <strong>in</strong>ability to identify α because the regression Equation (2) is (observationally) equivalent to<br />

net flowi,t = α ∗ + g(performancei,t−1) + α − α ∗ ...<br />

Therefore, I normalize g(performancei,t−1) so that we have g(0) = 0.<br />

To account for correlations among funds <strong>and</strong> autocorrelations over time, I report st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

errors after cluster<strong>in</strong>g observations by year <strong>and</strong> fund.<br />

C. L<strong>in</strong>ear regression methodology<br />

I run OLS regressions of net flows on each performance measure <strong>and</strong> the control variables, after<br />

assum<strong>in</strong>g that g(·) <strong>in</strong> Equation (2) is quadratic <strong>in</strong> lagged performance. Previous studies also use<br />

the square of lagged performance to capture nonl<strong>in</strong>earity of flow-performance relationships (e.g.,<br />

11


Barber, Odean <strong>and</strong> Zheng (2005) <strong>and</strong> Sensoy (2009)). I run the follow<strong>in</strong>g regressions us<strong>in</strong>g panel<br />

data:<br />

net flowi,t = α + β 1performancei,t−1 + β 2performance 2<br />

i,t−1<br />

+β 3performancei,t + β 4performancei,t−2 + β 5age i,t−1 + β 6size i,t−1<br />

+β 7expensei,t−1 + β 8volatilityi,t−1 + β 9<strong>in</strong>dustryi,t + β 10stylei,t<br />

+β 11net flowi,t−1 + εi,t, (4)<br />

where the variables are the same as <strong>in</strong> the Equation (2). Similar to kernel regressions, I report<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard errors after cluster<strong>in</strong>g by year <strong>and</strong> fund.<br />

D. <strong>Changes</strong> <strong>in</strong> the flow-performance relationship<br />

I first present the kernel regression results for the two subperiods. Figure III shows the esti-<br />

mates of the flow-performance relationship, i.e., the function g(performancet−1) <strong>in</strong> Equation (2),<br />

along with their 90% confidence <strong>in</strong>tervals <strong>in</strong> each period. For all four performance measures, the<br />

strik<strong>in</strong>g changes are <strong>in</strong> shapes: convexity before 2000 <strong>and</strong> l<strong>in</strong>earity or concavity after 2000. In par-<br />

ticular, expected <strong>in</strong>flows after good performance are much fewer after 2000 than before that year,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the decreases <strong>in</strong> expected <strong>in</strong>flows are larger for higher performance. For example, expected<br />

<strong>in</strong>flows after outperform<strong>in</strong>g the CRSP VW by 10% are 14.3% before 2000, but they decrease to<br />

6.6% after 2000. Net <strong>in</strong>flows to funds with 20% outperformance decreased from 27.8% to 9.4%.<br />

On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the flow-performance relationship for poor performance are similar between the<br />

two periods. Table II presents the coeffi cients on the control variables (the l<strong>in</strong>ear part <strong>in</strong> Equation<br />

(2)).<br />

12


The most dramatic changes are for performance relative to peer funds with the same styles. As<br />

shown <strong>in</strong> Figure III, the sensitivity of the relationship (i.e., the slope of the function g(performancet−1))<br />

is sharply <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g with the performance before 2000. Yet, after 2000, the sensitivity decl<strong>in</strong>es.<br />

For <strong>in</strong>stance, for 10% outperformance relative to peer funds, the sensitivity is around 3.6 before<br />

2000 but only 1.1 after that.<br />

The shape of the relationship between fund flows <strong>and</strong> excess returns over styles is odd for the<br />

performance region less than -20% or more than 20% prior to 2000. This is because there are not<br />

many data po<strong>in</strong>ts at those extremes. The 5 percentile <strong>and</strong> 95 percentile of excess returns over style<br />

returns are around -13% <strong>and</strong> 12% respectively (other performance measures are almost -20% <strong>and</strong><br />

16% respectively).<br />

The results from the OLS regressions are similar. I only report the results for performance<br />

relative to the CRSP VW <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>and</strong> for performance relative to style returns s<strong>in</strong>ce us<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

S&P500 <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>and</strong> funds’benchmark <strong>in</strong>dexes lead to almost the same results as us<strong>in</strong>g the CRSP<br />

VW <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>and</strong> style returns respectively. Table III shows the estimates followed by st<strong>and</strong>ard errors<br />

(clustered by year <strong>and</strong> fund) <strong>and</strong> p-values for each <strong>in</strong>dependent variable. The dependent variable is<br />

net flows. One of the strik<strong>in</strong>g differences is for the slope estimates on square of lagged performance.<br />

They are positive <strong>in</strong> the pre-2000 period but decrease to around -0.3 ∼ -0.4. The differences of<br />

those coeffi cients are significant at 1% significance level (the test is whether the <strong>in</strong>teraction term<br />

between the squared performance <strong>and</strong> the second period dummy is zero). The estimates on lagged<br />

performance are positive <strong>in</strong> both periods but the magnitudes are a bit smaller after 2000. I plot<br />

the estimated flow-performance relationship (the quadratic function) <strong>in</strong> Figure IV (A).<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ce the sensitivity of flow-performance relationship is given by the first derivative of the<br />

13


Equation (4) with respect to performance,<br />

β 1 + 2β 2performance t−1, (5)<br />

the estimates suggest that the sensitivity changes, for example, from 1.5 + 1.3performance t−1<br />

to 0.9 − 0.6performance t−1 when performance is excess returns over CRSP VW. Figure IV (B)<br />

illustrates these changes <strong>in</strong> sensitivity by plott<strong>in</strong>g the sensitivity as a function of past performance<br />

(i.e., Equation (5)) before 2000 <strong>and</strong> after 2000. For all four performance measures, the sensitivity<br />

<strong>in</strong>creases with past performance before 2000 (convexity), but it decreases with past performance<br />

after that (concavity). Yet, the most dramatic changes are for performance relative to peer funds<br />

with the same styles, which are consistent with the kernel regression results. The sensitivity for<br />

10% outperformance is around 2.5 on average from 1983 to 1999 but decreases to around 1 <strong>in</strong> the<br />

post-2000 period.<br />

Another difference between the two periods is that net flows are positively related to expense<br />

ratios of funds before 2000 but negatively related to that after the year. Both kernel regressions<br />

(Table II) <strong>and</strong> OLS regressions (Table III) show these contrast<strong>in</strong>g impacts of expense ratios. For<br />

example, as shown <strong>in</strong> Table III, when measur<strong>in</strong>g performance compared to the CRSP VW <strong>in</strong>dex,<br />

a 1% <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> expense ratios leads to a 8% <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> net flows <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g year on average<br />

from 1983 to 1999. After 2000, expense ratios have negative impact on fund flows. A 1% <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong><br />

expense ratios loses around 3% of net flows <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g year. Barber, Odean, Zheng (2005) <strong>and</strong><br />

Huang, Wei, <strong>and</strong> Yan (2005) also f<strong>in</strong>d a positive effect of (operat<strong>in</strong>g) expense ratios– not <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g<br />

front-end loads– on fund flows for sample periods before 2000. Barber, Odean, <strong>and</strong> Zheng argue<br />

that <strong>in</strong>vestors pay less attention to ongo<strong>in</strong>g operat<strong>in</strong>g expenses that are embedded <strong>in</strong> fund returns<br />

than front-end load fees. Rather, they are even attracted to funds with higher market<strong>in</strong>g expenses,<br />

14


lead<strong>in</strong>g to a positive relationship between expense ratios <strong>and</strong> fund flows. I discuss variations <strong>in</strong> the<br />

effect of the expense ratio on fund flows <strong>in</strong> Appendix.<br />

Coeffi cients estimates for other variables have the same signs <strong>in</strong> both periods (Table II <strong>and</strong><br />

Table III; results for other performance measures are available upon request). For example, smaller<br />

funds or younger funds grow more, consistent with earlier studies. A fund with less volatile returns<br />

over the last two years attracts more <strong>in</strong>flows. <strong>Fund</strong>s with more popular style characteristics received<br />

more <strong>in</strong> the pre-2000 period. However, style flows appear <strong>in</strong>significant <strong>in</strong> the post-2000 period when<br />

performance is measured relative to CRSP VW (or S&P500 <strong>in</strong>dex). In essence, <strong>in</strong>vestors seem to<br />

chase funds that outperform the markets irrespective of their styles <strong>in</strong> the 2000s.<br />

E. Determ<strong>in</strong>ants of sensitivity of the flow-performance relationship<br />

I showed that the flow-performance relationship changes around 2000. In particular, substantial<br />

changes are marg<strong>in</strong>al flow with respect to performance (i.e., the slope of g(performancet−1) or<br />

Equation (5)). For example, Figure IV (B) shows that marg<strong>in</strong>al flow <strong>in</strong>creases with performance<br />

before 2000 but decreases after 2000. Thus, I <strong>in</strong>vestigate what impacts the sensitivity of the flow-<br />

performance relationship. I focus on market- or <strong>in</strong>dustry-wide factors, rather than fund-specific<br />

ones, to exam<strong>in</strong>e variations <strong>in</strong> the sensitivity through time.<br />

To this end, I look at how β 2 <strong>in</strong> Equation (5) changes, more specifically, how it varies depend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

on market- or <strong>in</strong>dustry-wide conditions. Assum<strong>in</strong>g l<strong>in</strong>earity, I estimate<br />

β 1 + 2β 2,tperformance t−1 = β 1 + 2(γ + δ ′ Zt)performance t−1, (6)<br />

where Zt is a vector of condition<strong>in</strong>g variables that are known at time t. S<strong>in</strong>ce the Equation (6)<br />

is the first derivative of the regression Equation (4), I run the follow<strong>in</strong>g regression over the whole<br />

15


sample period, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>teraction terms between those variables <strong>and</strong> squared performance<br />

net flowi,t = α + β1performancei,t−1 + γperformance 2<br />

+ δ′ Zt ∗ performance i,t−1 2<br />

i,t−1<br />

+β 3performancei,t + ...... + β 11net flowi,t−1 + εi,t. (7)<br />

To motivate market volatility as a market-wide variable, I present <strong>in</strong> Figure V (A) the cross-<br />

sectional estimates on the square of excess returns relative to the CRSP VW (i.e., β 2 <strong>in</strong> Equation<br />

(4)) along with their 10% confidence <strong>in</strong>tervals, <strong>and</strong> lagged market volatility (annualized st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

deviation of the daily CRSP VW returns). The estimate on the square term dramatically decreases<br />

<strong>in</strong> 1998 <strong>and</strong> becomes negative <strong>in</strong> 2000, suggest<strong>in</strong>g convexity <strong>in</strong> the flow-performance relationship.<br />

The estimate <strong>and</strong> the lagged market volatility have almost the opposite patterns through time.<br />

While the estimates <strong>in</strong> the first period (1983-1999) <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> the second period (2000-2008) are positive<br />

<strong>and</strong> negative respectively, there have been some periods with negative coeffi cients before 2000 <strong>and</strong><br />

positive coeffi cients after 2000, which seem to depend on market volatility. For <strong>in</strong>stance, after the<br />

1987 market crash, the estimate on squared performance significantly drops <strong>in</strong> 1988. Follow<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

less volatile markets <strong>in</strong> 2005 <strong>and</strong> 2006, the slope estimates <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> 2006 <strong>and</strong> 2007.<br />

These results are consistent with the predictions that marg<strong>in</strong>al flow to superior performance<br />

is low when performance is noisy (Berk <strong>and</strong> Green (2004) <strong>and</strong> Kim (2010)). Figure V (C) shows<br />

performance distributions. In low-volatility markets (less than 10%), funds underperform markets<br />

on average, <strong>and</strong> outperformance is rare: The mean <strong>and</strong> the skewness of excess returns relative<br />

to the CRSP VW are -3% <strong>and</strong> -0.03 respectively. When markets are highly volatile (more than<br />

16%), funds outperform the markets on average (3%) <strong>and</strong> the performance is skewed to the right<br />

(skewness 0.7). Thus, performance tends to improve <strong>and</strong> appears noisier <strong>in</strong> highly volatile markets.<br />

I also look at how the sensitivity of the flow-performance relationship depends on heterogene-<br />

16


ity <strong>in</strong> skills. To obta<strong>in</strong> a proxy for that, I first regress the cross-sectional st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of<br />

performance on the market return <strong>and</strong> the market volatility (the mean <strong>and</strong> the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation<br />

of daily returns on the CRSP VW <strong>in</strong>dex respectively). Given that performance is represented as<br />

skills plus noise, its variance is the sum of the variance of skills <strong>and</strong> the variance of noise. Provided<br />

that the variance of skills is uncorrelated with market conditions, only the variance of noise depends<br />

on market conditions. Thus, I use the regression residual, which I call performance dispersion, as<br />

a condition<strong>in</strong>g variable.<br />

In addition to market volatility <strong>and</strong> performance dispersion, I use <strong>in</strong>dustry flow as condition<strong>in</strong>g<br />

variables. Industry flow is the same variable used <strong>in</strong> the previous regressions. S<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>in</strong>dicator<br />

variables are easy to <strong>in</strong>terpret (e.g., high- <strong>and</strong> low-volatility markets), I rank market return, market<br />

volatility <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry flow <strong>in</strong>to three groups respectively <strong>and</strong> assign values of -1 (low), 0 (medium),<br />

<strong>and</strong> +1 (high). Approximately, the medium volatility is between 10% <strong>and</strong> 16%; the medium return<br />

between 2% <strong>and</strong> 20%; <strong>and</strong> the medium <strong>in</strong>dustry flow between 3% <strong>and</strong> 9% (the conclusions do not<br />

change if I use their levels, or if I use dummies for high- <strong>and</strong> low-volatility markets). High volatility<br />

<strong>and</strong> low <strong>in</strong>dustry flow are prevalent <strong>in</strong> the 2000s. Figure V (B) shows the market volatility <strong>in</strong>dicator<br />

<strong>and</strong> performance dispersion.<br />

The results are provided <strong>in</strong> Table IV (the results for performance relative to S&P500 <strong>in</strong>dex<br />

are similar to Panel (A), <strong>and</strong> those for performance relative to the benchmark <strong>in</strong>dex are similar<br />

to Panel (B)). Before discuss<strong>in</strong>g the ma<strong>in</strong> regressions, I first present some benchmark cases. The<br />

first regression pools all years. The slope estimates on squared performance from 1983 to 2008 are<br />

negative <strong>and</strong> significant for all four performance measures, suggest<strong>in</strong>g the concave flow-performance<br />

relationship on average over the whole period. The concavity effect <strong>in</strong> the second period dom<strong>in</strong>ates<br />

because there are more observations after 2000. The effect of expense ratio appears negligible<br />

s<strong>in</strong>ce its contrast<strong>in</strong>g impacts <strong>in</strong> two subperiods are cancelled out each other over the entire sample<br />

17


period. When add<strong>in</strong>g lagged flows (the second regression), the adjusted R-squared <strong>in</strong>creases by<br />

around 7-8% while most estimates change little, except expense ratios. I <strong>in</strong>clude lagged flows <strong>in</strong><br />

the rest of regressions.<br />

Consistent with the results <strong>in</strong> Table II, us<strong>in</strong>g the second period dummy variable changes the<br />

estimates on squared performance <strong>and</strong> expense ratios dramatically (the third regression). The flow-<br />

performance relationship before 2000 appears convex but become concave <strong>in</strong> the second period. The<br />

expense ratios are positively related to fund flows over 1983 to 1999 but have a negative impact <strong>in</strong><br />

the 2000s. These results are similar for all performance measures.<br />

I now discuss the ma<strong>in</strong> regressions that exam<strong>in</strong>e the determ<strong>in</strong>ants of the flow-performance<br />

sensitivity. When <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>teraction terms between squared performance <strong>and</strong> lagged stock<br />

market <strong>in</strong>dicators (the regression (4)), the coeffi cients on those terms are negative (market returns<br />

appear <strong>in</strong>significant for the sensitivity). Note that the estimates on squared performance are statis-<br />

tically <strong>in</strong>significant. We cannot reject that <strong>in</strong> the medium volatility markets, the flow-performance<br />

relationship is l<strong>in</strong>ear. In periods follow<strong>in</strong>g highly volatile markets, the coeffi cient on the squared<br />

excess returns over the CRSP VW decreases by around -0.9, which <strong>in</strong>dicates concavity <strong>in</strong> the flow-<br />

performance relationship. In low volatility markets, the coeffi cient <strong>in</strong>creases by +0.9, which implies<br />

convexity <strong>in</strong> the relationship (see Figure VI). 11 I <strong>in</strong>terpret these results as support<strong>in</strong>g evidence that<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestors become less responsive to superior performance <strong>in</strong> highly volatile markets because they<br />

perceive performance aris<strong>in</strong>g primarily from luck.<br />

After add<strong>in</strong>g performance dispersion (uncorrelated with market volatility <strong>and</strong> returns) as a<br />

condition<strong>in</strong>g variable (regression (5)), I f<strong>in</strong>d that a 1% <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the cross-sectional st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

deviation <strong>in</strong> performance <strong>in</strong>creases the coeffi cient on squared performance by around 7%. Thus,<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestors appear more responsive to superior performance when performance is more dispersed.<br />

11 When us<strong>in</strong>g dummy variables for market volatility, I f<strong>in</strong>d consistent results that convexity decreases <strong>in</strong> highly<br />

volatile markets (see Section III.A for details).<br />

18


Provided that performance dispersion can proxy for heterogeneity <strong>in</strong> skills, high dispersion <strong>in</strong>dicates<br />

that performance is more attributable to skills.<br />

Industry flow appears to <strong>in</strong>crease the sensitivity of the flow—performance relationship (regres-<br />

sion (6)). This can suggest that more money <strong>in</strong> mutual funds actually goes to high-perform<strong>in</strong>g<br />

funds. Provided that fund performance exhibits decreas<strong>in</strong>g returns to scale (Chen et. al. (2004)),<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> funds with higher expected returns when they <strong>in</strong>vest more. The last regressions<br />

show the results <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g all condition<strong>in</strong>g variables. Market volatility <strong>and</strong> performance dispersion<br />

rema<strong>in</strong> significant when measur<strong>in</strong>g performance relative to style returns. Yet, when the CRSP<br />

VW is used as the benchmark, market volatility becomes <strong>in</strong>significant. This could be due to the<br />

significant correlation between market volatility <strong>and</strong> the second period dummy.<br />

II. <strong>Managerial</strong> <strong>in</strong>centives<br />

I exam<strong>in</strong>e whether managers change their risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g accord<strong>in</strong>g to variations <strong>in</strong> the flow-<br />

performance relationship. Brown, Harlow <strong>and</strong> Starks (1996) <strong>and</strong> Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison (1997)<br />

show that some mutual fund managers <strong>in</strong>crease the risk<strong>in</strong>ess of their funds toward the end of<br />

the year as a result of the <strong>in</strong>centives provided by the flow-performance relationship. They also<br />

argue that the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the risk<strong>in</strong>ess is positively related to expected net flows <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

year. Given a decrease <strong>in</strong> fund flows to outperform<strong>in</strong>g funds <strong>in</strong> the 2000s, managers should engage<br />

<strong>in</strong> less risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g. In addition, variation <strong>in</strong> risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g accord<strong>in</strong>g to performance up to the<br />

third quarter should be also different <strong>in</strong> the 2000s. When the sensitivity of the flow-performance<br />

relationship is larger for high performance than for low performance, underperform<strong>in</strong>g managers<br />

have proper <strong>in</strong>centives to <strong>in</strong>crease the risk<strong>in</strong>ess of their funds while good performers lock <strong>in</strong> their<br />

ga<strong>in</strong>s. Otherwise, managers who are beh<strong>in</strong>d the markets would have fewer <strong>in</strong>centives for such<br />

risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g. Therefore, I also look at how performance up to the third quarter affects risk-tak<strong>in</strong>g<br />

19


ehavior <strong>in</strong> the fourth quarter depend<strong>in</strong>g on variations <strong>in</strong> the flow-performance relationship.<br />

I measure the risk<strong>in</strong>ess of funds equity hold<strong>in</strong>gs rather than fund returns. Busse (2001) obta<strong>in</strong><br />

different results than those <strong>in</strong> Brown, Harlow <strong>and</strong> Starks (1996) when us<strong>in</strong>g daily returns <strong>in</strong>stead of<br />

monthly returns. Thus, I exam<strong>in</strong>e risk measures that use hold<strong>in</strong>g data, such as those suggested by<br />

Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison (1997) <strong>and</strong> Huang, Sialm <strong>and</strong> Zhang (2009). Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison’s measure<br />

compares fund risk at the end of December <strong>and</strong> at the end of September. Huang, Sialm <strong>and</strong> Zhang’s<br />

measure compares fund risk with a long term risk level, namely, over the prior 36 months.<br />

A. Data <strong>and</strong> variable description<br />

I use the Thomson-Reuters <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> Hold<strong>in</strong>gs for equity hold<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> the CRSP Survivor-<br />

Bias-Free US <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> for TNA <strong>and</strong> monthly returns (Morn<strong>in</strong>gstar does not provide historical<br />

hold<strong>in</strong>g data). I <strong>in</strong>clude only the funds with the objective codes of aggressive growth, growth or<br />

growth <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, as provided by the Thomson-Reuters. I exclude <strong>in</strong>dex funds by fund name,<br />

small funds (less than $10 million at the end of September) <strong>and</strong> young funds (fewer than 2 years).<br />

The sample period is from 1983 to 2008.<br />

The first risk measure uses volatility of excess returns over the CRSP VW. It decomposes the<br />

volatility <strong>in</strong>to two parts (Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison (1997)):<br />

var(ri − rm) = var(ri − β irm) + (β i − 1) 2 var(rm),<br />

where ri is the fund i’s return, rm the market return proxied by the CRSP VW <strong>in</strong>dex, <strong>and</strong> β i is the<br />

fund i’s CAPM beta. Total risk, unsystematic risk <strong>and</strong> systematic risk, are def<strong>in</strong>ed as their square<br />

roots, ST D(ri − rm), ST D(ri − β irm), <strong>and</strong> |β i − 1| respectively.<br />

Risk-shifts are the risk difference between September <strong>and</strong> December, denoted by RISKDec −<br />

RISKSep for total risk, unsystematic risk <strong>and</strong> systematic risk. To estimate RISKSep <strong>and</strong> RISKDec,<br />

20


I construct two portfolios that hold the stocks <strong>in</strong> the fund at the end of September <strong>and</strong> December<br />

respectively <strong>and</strong> calculate the volatility of those hypothetical portfolios us<strong>in</strong>g daily return data<br />

<strong>in</strong> the prior year. As Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison po<strong>in</strong>t out, RISKDec − RISKSep does not depend<br />

on changes <strong>in</strong> market conditions but only on changes <strong>in</strong> equity hold<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> the fourth quarter.<br />

To estimate total risk ST D(ri − rm), I use the (annualized) st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of daily excess<br />

returns on the hypothetical portfolio over the CRSP VW returns. Likewise, unsystematic risk,<br />

ST D(ri − β irm), is the (annualized) st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of ri − β irm where β i is the beta of the<br />

portfolio. One disadvantage of this measures is that betas of <strong>in</strong>dividual stocks should be estimated.<br />

I only consider the funds of which hypothetical portfolios have 80% of funds’TNA.<br />

Another measure is suggested by Huang, Sialm <strong>and</strong> Zhang (2009). It represents how much<br />

riskier the fund would have been if it had held the current assets over the prior 36 months. It<br />

measures the difference between the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of returns on a hypothetical portfolio that<br />

holds the current assets of the fund <strong>and</strong> the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of actual returns on the fund over<br />

the prior 36 months: hypothetical risk − actual risk. A positive risk shift of a fund implies that the<br />

fund has higher risk, compared to the prior three years. I focus on the risk-shift measure at the<br />

end of December. I only consider a fund if the value of its hypothetical portfolio is at least 80% of<br />

its TNA.<br />

I <strong>in</strong>clude some control variables <strong>in</strong> the regression. Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison (1997) argue that<br />

small or young funds may have stronger <strong>in</strong>centives for <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g risk<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>and</strong> that the risk level<br />

at the end of September would be also relevant for risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g. Thus, I use the log of equity value<br />

<strong>in</strong> million <strong>and</strong> the log of months s<strong>in</strong>ce the <strong>in</strong>ception date (or the first month that TNA data is<br />

available) as control variables. To control the risk level from which managers deviate, I use total<br />

risk, idiosyncratic risk <strong>and</strong> systematic risk <strong>in</strong> September (for the other risk-shift measure, I use<br />

actual risk).<br />

21


The descriptive statistics are provided <strong>in</strong> Table V. The sample size is small because the re-<br />

gressions require a match between the Thomson-Reuters hold<strong>in</strong>g database <strong>and</strong> the CRSP data.<br />

Moreover, I have some screen<strong>in</strong>g criteria as discussed above. The average fund has $1.2-1.5 billion<br />

of TNA <strong>and</strong> is 16-18 years old. A typical fund has 8.3% of total risk <strong>and</strong> 7.5% of idiosyncratic risk<br />

(annualized) at the end of September. These values are larger by around 3% than <strong>in</strong> Chevalier <strong>and</strong><br />

Ellison. Systematic risk, def<strong>in</strong>ed as |β i − 1|, is similar to Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison. The magnitudes of<br />

risk shift are smaller <strong>in</strong> my sample than <strong>in</strong> Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison, for <strong>in</strong>stance, -0.05% versus 0.2%<br />

for total risk. The risk-shift measure by Huang, Sialm <strong>and</strong> Zhang is around 0.4% on average, which<br />

is larger than the average of -0.33% <strong>in</strong> their paper. I only look at equity hold<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> restrict my<br />

sample to the funds of which hypothetical portfolios cover at least 80% of their TNA. Yet, Huang,<br />

Sialm <strong>and</strong> Zhang also consider bond <strong>and</strong> cash hold<strong>in</strong>gs by prox<strong>in</strong>g them us<strong>in</strong>g the Lehman Brothers<br />

Aggregate Bond Index <strong>and</strong> the Treasury Bill rate, <strong>and</strong> do not have restrictions on the hypothetical<br />

portfolio value. Another difference is that my sample <strong>in</strong>cludes only the end of December, while<br />

Huang, Sialm <strong>and</strong> Zhang also consider all months, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the months for which the quarterly<br />

hold<strong>in</strong>g data are unavailable (e.g., January <strong>and</strong> February) <strong>and</strong> use the most recent hold<strong>in</strong>g data for<br />

a given month.<br />

B. Methodology<br />

The ma<strong>in</strong> goal is to exam<strong>in</strong>e whether the flow-performance relationship provides managers with<br />

risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>centives toward the end of the year. Given the dramatic changes <strong>in</strong> the relationship<br />

after 2000 <strong>and</strong> its variations accord<strong>in</strong>g to market conditions <strong>and</strong> performance dispersion, I look<br />

at how managers’ risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g behavior <strong>in</strong> the fourth quarter changes after 2000, <strong>and</strong> how such<br />

changes are related to those variables that affect the flow-performance relationship.<br />

Provided that managers take more risk as an attempt to <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong>flows <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g year,<br />

22


isk-shift<strong>in</strong>g should also depend on performance accord<strong>in</strong>g to the shape <strong>in</strong> the flow-performance<br />

relationship. For example, when the relationship is convex, it would be underperform<strong>in</strong>g managers<br />

who have strong <strong>in</strong>centives to gamble by tak<strong>in</strong>g more risk. Thus, I also exam<strong>in</strong>e how the relationship<br />

between risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> performance varies accord<strong>in</strong>g to the variables that determ<strong>in</strong>e the flow-<br />

performance sensitivity. To this end, I <strong>in</strong>clude the <strong>in</strong>teraction terms between performance <strong>and</strong><br />

those condition<strong>in</strong>g variables as regressors. I run the follow<strong>in</strong>g regression:<br />

risk shifti,t,Dec = α + β 1periodt + β ′ 2controlsi,t + β 3reti,t,SEP<br />

+β 4reti,t,SEP ∗ periodt + β ′ 5reti,t,SEP ∗ Zt,SEP + εi,t, (8)<br />

where risk shifti,t,Dec is RISKi,tDec − RISKi,tSep when us<strong>in</strong>g total, unsystematic, <strong>and</strong> systematic<br />

risk, <strong>and</strong> is hypothetical risk i,t,Dec − actual risk i,t,Dec by Huang, Sialm <strong>and</strong> Zhang. The variable<br />

periodt is one when the year t is <strong>in</strong> the second period (from 2000 to 2008). The condition<strong>in</strong>g<br />

variables Zt,SEP <strong>in</strong>clude market return (demeaned), market volatility (demeaned), <strong>and</strong> performance<br />

dispersion (residual) as expla<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> Section 1. 12 Given that I look at managers’ risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g<br />

behavior <strong>in</strong> the fourth quarter, I measure these variables as of the third quarter. In essence, these<br />

variables can be used to form expectations about the flow-performance relationship <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

year. The below time l<strong>in</strong>e illustrates the case of RISKi,tDec − RISKi,tSep.<br />

Jan (t-1) Dec (t-1) Jan (t) Sep (t) Dec (t)<br />

<br />

equity returns for risk Sep(t) <strong>and</strong> risk D ec(t)<br />

risk Sep(t)<br />

<br />

Zt, SE P<br />

risk Dec(t)<br />

I also <strong>in</strong>clude year dummy <strong>and</strong> report st<strong>and</strong>ard errors that are clustered by fund (I do not<br />

12 I exclude <strong>in</strong>dustry flow at time t + 1 s<strong>in</strong>ce it is not known when managers engage <strong>in</strong> risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

23


<strong>in</strong>clude lagged risk shift s<strong>in</strong>ce its slope estimates are close to zero <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>significant).<br />

C. <strong>Changes</strong> <strong>in</strong> managers’risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g behavior<br />

Table VI presents the l<strong>in</strong>ear regression results for managers’risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g behavior. The first<br />

table (A) provides the results for total risk, unsystematic risk <strong>and</strong> systematic risk. First, the<br />

coeffi cient on performance (excess returns over the CRSP VW) at the end of September is negative<br />

<strong>and</strong> significant for total risk, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that managers who are beh<strong>in</strong>d the markets <strong>in</strong>crease risk<br />

<strong>in</strong> the fourth quarter prior to 2000. Yet, this risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g lessens by around 70% <strong>in</strong> the 2000s,<br />

as the negative coeffi cient on the second period dummy shows. This seems consistent with the<br />

weaker flow-performance relationship after 2000. Provided that convexity <strong>in</strong> the relationship leads<br />

underperform<strong>in</strong>g managers to <strong>in</strong>crease risk, they should engage <strong>in</strong> less risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g when the shape<br />

is not convex. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, when decompos<strong>in</strong>g risk, performance seems to have little impact<br />

on risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g for the systematic part.<br />

The regression model (2) shows how these changes <strong>in</strong> risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g are related to the variables<br />

that affect the flow-performance relationship. For all three risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g measures, performance<br />

dispersion across funds plays a significant role. The coeffi cients on its <strong>in</strong>teraction term with fund<br />

performance are negative. In essence, when performance is dispersed, those managers who are<br />

beh<strong>in</strong>d the markets (CRSP VW <strong>in</strong>dex) <strong>in</strong>crease risk– both unsystematic <strong>and</strong> systematic risk– <strong>in</strong><br />

the fourth quarter. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, market volatility appears important for systematic risk.<br />

After <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g those condition<strong>in</strong>g variables, I f<strong>in</strong>d that underperform<strong>in</strong>g managers also <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

systematic risk when market volatility is low <strong>and</strong> when performance is more dispersed. The f<strong>in</strong>al<br />

regression (3) also <strong>in</strong>cludes the second period dummy <strong>and</strong> shows that those condition<strong>in</strong>g variables<br />

can expla<strong>in</strong> changes <strong>in</strong> managers’risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g behavior after 2000. Given that the flow-performance<br />

relationship is more likely to be convex follow<strong>in</strong>g large performance dispersion <strong>and</strong> low market<br />

24


volatility, my results support the view that managers respond to the flow-performance relationship<br />

by chang<strong>in</strong>g the risk<strong>in</strong>ess of their funds toward the end of the year.<br />

The results for risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g from the risk level over the prior 36 months are as follows. Prior<br />

to 2000, funds’risk at the end of December was higher by around 0.03 compared to the long-term<br />

level. After that year, the magnitude decreases by around 30%. Yet, this change appears to be<br />

unrelated to changes <strong>in</strong> the flow-performance relationship. The risk-shift measure is positively re-<br />

lated to performance throughout the sample period from 1983 to 2008. Good performers <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

risk compared to the long-term risk level. Moreover, the relationship between performance <strong>and</strong><br />

a deviation from the long-term risk level does not depend on performance dispersion, which de-<br />

term<strong>in</strong>es the expected sensitivity of the flow-performance relationship. Rather, such relationship<br />

<strong>in</strong>creases with market volatility, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that underperformers take risk when market volatility<br />

is low while outperformers take even more risk when it is high (results are available upon request).<br />

The results that performance dispersion is <strong>in</strong>significant for risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g from the level over the<br />

prior 3 years do not support the argument that the flow-performance relationship provides managers<br />

with <strong>in</strong>centives to deviate from a long-term risk level. Thus, I <strong>in</strong>terpret that to <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong>flows<br />

dur<strong>in</strong>g the follow<strong>in</strong>g year, managers <strong>in</strong>crease risk relative to the risk level at the end September,<br />

but not relative to a long-term risk level.<br />

III. Robustness check<br />

A. Dummy variables for market conditions<br />

In Section I.E, I use <strong>in</strong>dicator variables for market returns <strong>and</strong> market volatility. Instead, I<br />

use dummy variables. I def<strong>in</strong>e market volatility state-High <strong>and</strong> market volatility state-Low as the<br />

dummy variables that have a value of one if market volatility is high (more than 16%) <strong>and</strong> low<br />

(below 10%) respectively. Similarly, I def<strong>in</strong>e market return state-High <strong>and</strong> market return state-Low.<br />

25


Us<strong>in</strong>g those dummy variables, I f<strong>in</strong>d that the results are consistent with those obta<strong>in</strong>ed from<br />

the <strong>in</strong>dicator variables (i.e., Table IV). Market returns do not appear to have a significant impact<br />

on the shape of the flow-performance relationship, but market volatility decreases its convexity. In<br />

highly-volatile markets, the relationship is concave. In low-volatility markets, the shape seems more<br />

convex, but we cannot reject the hypothesis that it is l<strong>in</strong>ear (results are available upon request).<br />

B. Piecewise regression<br />

I also estimate the flow-performance relationship for seven <strong>in</strong>tervals of performance, lower than<br />

−0.2, between −0.2 <strong>and</strong> −0.1, <strong>and</strong> so forth. More specifically, I run piecewise OLS regression:<br />

net flowi,t = α + β A 1 performance A i,t−1 + β B 1 performance B i,t−1 + ... + β G 1 performance G i,t−1<br />

+β 3performancei,t + β 4performancei,t−2 + β 5age i,t−1 + β 6size i,t−1<br />

+β 7expensei,t−1 + β 8volatilityi,t−1 + β 9<strong>in</strong>dustryi,t + β 10stylei,t<br />

+β 11net flowi,t−1 + εi,t,<br />

where performance <strong>in</strong>tervals are def<strong>in</strong>ed as performance A i,t−1 = m<strong>in</strong>[performance i,t−1 , −0.2], performanceB i,t−1 =<br />

m<strong>in</strong>[performancei,t−1 − performanceA i,t−1 , 0.1], <strong>and</strong> so on.<br />

I also <strong>in</strong>teract all those performance variables with the condition<strong>in</strong>g variables (e.g., market<br />

volatility, performance dispersion, <strong>and</strong> second-period dummy) to exam<strong>in</strong>e time variation <strong>in</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>al<br />

flow (the coeffi cients from β A 1 to β G 1 ).<br />

The results confirm that the relationship is not convex on average over the whole sample pe-<br />

riod from 1983 to 2008 <strong>and</strong> the shape changes from convexity to concavity around the year 2000<br />

(results are available upon request). Us<strong>in</strong>g the coeffi cient estimates, I plot the flow-performance<br />

relationship <strong>in</strong> Figure VII (A). In addition, similar to the OLS results, market volatility <strong>and</strong> per-<br />

26


formance dispersion affect marg<strong>in</strong>al flow. Figure VII (B) shows the relationship conditional on<br />

market volatility with other condition<strong>in</strong>g variables fixed. Performance dispersion <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry flow<br />

are more salient for net flows to outperformance of more than 20%. When performance is more<br />

dispersed <strong>and</strong> when the mutual fund <strong>in</strong>dustry receives more <strong>in</strong>vestment money, funds that are way<br />

ahead of the market attract more <strong>in</strong>flows.<br />

C. Performance rank<strong>in</strong>g<br />

So far, I look at benchmark-adjusted returns as performance (e.g., Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison (1997),<br />

Barber, Odean, <strong>and</strong> Zheng (2005), Sensoy (2009)). Goetzmann <strong>and</strong> Peles (1996) <strong>and</strong> Sirri <strong>and</strong> Tu-<br />

fano (1998) among others use performance rank<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d that the flow-performance relationship<br />

is significant only for top-ranked funds, lead<strong>in</strong>g to a convex flow-performance relationship. To ex-<br />

am<strong>in</strong>e whether my results are robust to performance measures, I rank raw returns <strong>in</strong> the ascend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

order <strong>and</strong> divide the rank by the number of funds (i.e., the fund with highest return has the rank<br />

of one) <strong>and</strong> estimate the relationship between net flows <strong>and</strong> that performance rank<strong>in</strong>g. I also esti-<br />

mate the conditional version of the relationship <strong>and</strong> exam<strong>in</strong>e how performance rank<strong>in</strong>g is related<br />

to managers’risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Us<strong>in</strong>g rank<strong>in</strong>g as a performance measure does not change the conclusion that marg<strong>in</strong>al flow to<br />

high perform<strong>in</strong>g funds is lower <strong>in</strong> the post-2000 period than before 2000. I plot TNA-weighted net<br />

flows of funds <strong>in</strong> each b<strong>in</strong> from 1 to 10 accord<strong>in</strong>g to deciles of the performance rank<strong>in</strong>g as described<br />

above (not presented but available upon request). The average net flows to high-ranked funds<br />

decrease dramatically after 2000. The results of kernel regression <strong>and</strong> OLS regression also support<br />

the argument that marg<strong>in</strong>al flow to high-ranked funds is much lower <strong>in</strong> the post-2000 period. Figure<br />

VIII shows the flow-performance relationship estimated us<strong>in</strong>g kernel regression, after controll<strong>in</strong>g<br />

other factors such as fund characteristics <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry flow. For example, those funds ranked at<br />

27


the 90 percentile received 30% of <strong>in</strong>flows on average before 2000, which decrease to 10% after 2000.<br />

This difference is comparable to the results obta<strong>in</strong>ed us<strong>in</strong>g the absolute performance measures<br />

(e.g., excess returns over the CRSP VW returns). Outperform<strong>in</strong>g the market by 0.2 leads to 30%<br />

of <strong>in</strong>flows before 2000 but only 10% after that year.<br />

The shape of the flow-performance relationship is still convex even after 2000. Yet, convexity<br />

decreases dramatically. Before 2000, the relationship seems l<strong>in</strong>ear up to around the 70 percentile,<br />

after which the sensitivity <strong>in</strong>creases sharply. After 2000, the l<strong>in</strong>ear relationship holds up to the 90<br />

percentile. The slope after the 90 percentile <strong>in</strong> the post-2000 period is also less steep than the slope<br />

after the 70 percentile before 2000. The OLS regression results are also consistent (Table VII). The<br />

estimate on squared ranks is positive <strong>in</strong> both periods, but the magnitude decreases by about 70%<br />

after 2000 (regression (3)).<br />

I also exam<strong>in</strong>e whether convexity <strong>in</strong> the relationship between net flows <strong>and</strong> performance rank<strong>in</strong>g<br />

depends on the condition<strong>in</strong>g variables. I f<strong>in</strong>d that performance dispersion <strong>in</strong>creases convexity of the<br />

relationship between net flows <strong>and</strong> performance rank<strong>in</strong>g. As regression models (6) <strong>and</strong> (7) <strong>in</strong> Table<br />

VII show, when fund returns are more dispersed, <strong>in</strong>vestors are much more sensitive to high-ranked<br />

funds. Yet, the effect of market volatility on fund flows respond<strong>in</strong>g to performance rank<strong>in</strong>g seems<br />

noisy <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>significant. Given a right-skewed distribution of fund returns <strong>in</strong> highly-volatile markets<br />

(see Figure V (C) <strong>and</strong> (D)), funds’absolute performance can improve <strong>in</strong> such markets, but relative<br />

performance may not.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, I also confirm changes <strong>in</strong> managers’risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g behavior after 2000 when performance<br />

is measured as rank<strong>in</strong>g. Similar to low-perform<strong>in</strong>g funds (based on excess returns over the market),<br />

low-ranked funds tend to <strong>in</strong>crease the risk<strong>in</strong>ess of their fund <strong>in</strong> the fourth quarter, but this risk-<br />

shift<strong>in</strong>g lessens <strong>in</strong> the post-2000 period. This change <strong>in</strong> managers’risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g is also expla<strong>in</strong>ed by<br />

performance dispersion, similar to the results when us<strong>in</strong>g excess returns over the CRSP VW <strong>in</strong>dex<br />

28


as performance measure (results are available upon request).<br />

D. Flow-performance relationship for <strong>in</strong>dex funds<br />

I discuss the results for <strong>in</strong>dex funds to compare with non<strong>in</strong>dex funds. The descriptive statistics<br />

are provided <strong>in</strong> Table VIII. Index funds received large <strong>in</strong>flows <strong>in</strong> the 1990’s. Index funds are younger,<br />

but the average size is almost double compared to non<strong>in</strong>dex funds, reflect<strong>in</strong>g a growth <strong>in</strong> passive<br />

management. The average expense ratios are lower by around 0.08% than non<strong>in</strong>dex funds.<br />

I f<strong>in</strong>d that the flow-performance relationship is barely significant for <strong>in</strong>dex funds <strong>in</strong> most cases.<br />

As shown <strong>in</strong> Table IX, the coeffi cient on performance is <strong>in</strong>significant for excess returns over the<br />

market. Exceptionally, when performance of <strong>in</strong>dex funds is measured relative to their peers, fund<br />

flows seem to <strong>in</strong>crease with that performance (Panel (B)). There are few significant changes <strong>in</strong> the<br />

flow-performance relationship for <strong>in</strong>dex funds after 2000. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the expense ratio<br />

is the most important determ<strong>in</strong>ant for <strong>in</strong>dex fund flows throughout the years. An 1% <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong><br />

expense ratios leads to almost 20% decrease <strong>in</strong> fund flows <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g year.<br />

Unlike non<strong>in</strong>dex funds, lagged flows do not have explanatory power for flows <strong>in</strong>to <strong>and</strong> out of<br />

<strong>in</strong>dex funds. This suggests that there are few fund fixed effects on <strong>in</strong>dex fund flows. Moreover,<br />

performance <strong>and</strong> the control variables have less explanatory power for <strong>in</strong>dex funds. While the<br />

adjusted R-squared is 22-25% for non<strong>in</strong>dex funds, it is less than 10% for <strong>in</strong>dex funds.<br />

In Figure IV, I present kernel regression results for <strong>in</strong>dex funds from 2000 to 2008. Due to a<br />

small sample size, the estimation is impossible for the first period (1983-1999), <strong>and</strong> the confidence<br />

<strong>in</strong>tervals of the estimates are large even <strong>in</strong> the second period. Nevertheless, <strong>in</strong>vestors appear to<br />

respond to the performance of <strong>in</strong>dex funds compared to their peer funds, consistent with the OLS<br />

regression results.<br />

29


IV. Conclusion<br />

I show that the flow-performance relationship for U.S. mutual funds, which was convex prior<br />

to 2000, is no longer convex. In particular, the marg<strong>in</strong>al flow to high-perform<strong>in</strong>g funds significantly<br />

decreases <strong>in</strong> the 2000s. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to my f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs, when markets are highly volatile <strong>and</strong> when per-<br />

formance is less dispersed, the sensitivity of flows to superior performance is low. These variations<br />

contribute to the changes <strong>in</strong> the shape of the relationship <strong>in</strong> the 2000s.<br />

<strong>Fund</strong> managers appear to respond to changes <strong>in</strong> the flow-performance sensitivity. Their risk-<br />

shift<strong>in</strong>g toward the end of the year lessens after 2000, <strong>and</strong> this change can also be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by<br />

the same variables that determ<strong>in</strong>e the sensitivity of the flow-performance relationship. In par-<br />

ticular, underperform<strong>in</strong>g managers engage <strong>in</strong> less risk-shift<strong>in</strong>g when performance across funds is<br />

less dispersed. They also take less systematic risk <strong>in</strong> the fourth quarter when market volatility is<br />

high. I argue that the flow-performance relationship can serve as a dynamic <strong>in</strong>centive contract <strong>and</strong><br />

managers react to the <strong>in</strong>centives provided by the implicit performance compensation scheme.<br />

30


Appendix<br />

A. Kernel regression<br />

I discuss kernel regressions. Given data of pairs of fund flows <strong>and</strong> past performance, kernel<br />

regressions estimate the function g(performance) as a weighted sum of fund flows. The weight<br />

for observed fund flow is large when the correspond<strong>in</strong>g performance is close to the condition<strong>in</strong>g<br />

value of performance. More specifically, the weight is proportional to the normal density (kernel<br />

function) with the mean equal to the condition<strong>in</strong>g value performance <strong>and</strong> the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation<br />

equal to a b<strong>and</strong>width. Asymptotically, the estimates do not depend on kernel functions used for<br />

weights under some conditions, <strong>and</strong> normal, uniform, <strong>and</strong> Epanechnikov kernels are often used.<br />

I select optimal b<strong>and</strong>widths us<strong>in</strong>g the cross-validation method (m<strong>in</strong>imize <strong>in</strong>tegrated squared<br />

errors). When we use a b<strong>and</strong>width h that goes to zero as the number of observations n <strong>in</strong>creases<br />

to <strong>in</strong>f<strong>in</strong>ity but not as fast as n (nh → ∞), the estimated function converges to the true one <strong>in</strong><br />

probability. The cross-validation method of choos<strong>in</strong>g b<strong>and</strong>width is consistent with these criteria <strong>and</strong><br />

preferred by researchers despite its high computational costs. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, fixed b<strong>and</strong>widths<br />

(i.e., arbitrarily choos<strong>in</strong>g b<strong>and</strong>widths) or a rule of thumb method for b<strong>and</strong>widths may not satisfy<br />

those criteria for consistency. S<strong>in</strong>ce the cross-validation method m<strong>in</strong>imizes <strong>in</strong>tegrated squared<br />

errors, it also results <strong>in</strong> more effi cient estimates.<br />

Many studies use simple averages to estimate g(performancei,t−1). For example, Sirri <strong>and</strong><br />

Tufano (1998) <strong>and</strong> Huang, Wei <strong>and</strong> Yan (2007) rank past performance <strong>in</strong>to 20 <strong>and</strong> 10 b<strong>in</strong>s respec-<br />

tively <strong>and</strong> use equally-weighted averages of fund flows <strong>in</strong> each b<strong>in</strong>. This method may be understood<br />

as kernel regressions with the uniform kernel. In this case, b<strong>and</strong>widths do not decrease as sample<br />

size <strong>in</strong>creases but vary across b<strong>in</strong>s. Take an example of 10 b<strong>in</strong>s. Then we estimate expected fund<br />

flows for 10 values of performance which are the mid po<strong>in</strong>ts of ranges of b<strong>in</strong>s. The b<strong>and</strong>width for<br />

31


the b<strong>in</strong> b is half of the b<strong>in</strong>’s range. S<strong>in</strong>ce the ranges do not shr<strong>in</strong>k as the sample size <strong>in</strong>creases, the<br />

b<strong>and</strong>width does not go to zero. Thus, estimated flow-performance relationships may not converge<br />

to the true function <strong>in</strong> probability.<br />

B. The effect of the expense ratio on fund flows<br />

The coeffi cient on the expense ratio over time has wide confidence <strong>in</strong>tervals (not reported).<br />

The time-series pattern does not look to be related to market volatility. In fact, the <strong>in</strong>teraction<br />

term between the expense ratio <strong>and</strong> market volatility is <strong>in</strong>significant, as is the <strong>in</strong>teraction term<br />

between the expense ratio <strong>and</strong> performance dispersion. These results suggest that market volatility<br />

<strong>and</strong> performance dispersion cannot expla<strong>in</strong> the variation <strong>in</strong> the effect of the expense ratio on net<br />

flows (results are available upon request).<br />

Rather, the negative effect of the expense ratio on fund flows after 2000 seems to be associated<br />

with a decrease <strong>in</strong> the fraction of 12b-1 fees after 1999. I look at average fractions of 12-1 fees over<br />

time, us<strong>in</strong>g a sample of non<strong>in</strong>dex equity funds with nonmiss<strong>in</strong>g 12b-1 fees <strong>in</strong> the CRSP database<br />

(the data start <strong>in</strong> 1992 <strong>and</strong> uses “0” for miss<strong>in</strong>g 12b-1 fees until 2000). I allow the coeffi cient on<br />

the expense ratio to vary accord<strong>in</strong>g to the TNA-weighted proportion of 12b-1 fees <strong>in</strong> the prior year.<br />

I f<strong>in</strong>d that expense ratios have a negative effect on fund flows, but the negative effect decreases<br />

as the average fraction of 12b-1 fees <strong>in</strong>creases. When 12b-1 fees count for more than 30% of fund<br />

expenses on average expense ratios have a positive effect on fund flows. The lagged 12b-1 proportion<br />

(weighted by fund size is about 31% before 2000. Yet, it decreases to 29% after 2000. This decrease<br />

<strong>in</strong> the proportion of 12b-1 fees seems to be associated with a negative impact of the expense ratio<br />

on fund flows after 2000 (results are available upon request). 13<br />

13 A survey by the Investment Company Institute (ICI) <strong>in</strong> 2004 f<strong>in</strong>ds that 92% of 12b-1 fees are used for pay<strong>in</strong>g<br />

f<strong>in</strong>ancial advisers, <strong>and</strong> only 2% for advertis<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> promotion. An ICI report (“<strong>Fund</strong>amentals,”14 (2), 2005) argues<br />

that mutual funds shifted the way of compensat<strong>in</strong>g f<strong>in</strong>ancial advisors from front-end load fees to 12b-1 fees. Large<br />

funds tend to charge lower expense ratios but higher 12b-1 fees. The TNA-weighted expense ratio is lower than the<br />

simple average ratio, but the fraction of 12b-1 fees is higher when weighted by fund size.<br />

32


References<br />

Barber, Brad, Terrance Odean, <strong>and</strong> Lu Zheng, 2005, Out of Sight, Out of M<strong>in</strong>d: The Effects of<br />

Expenses on <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> <strong>Flows</strong>, Journal of Bus<strong>in</strong>ess, 78 (6), 2095-2119.<br />

Bergstresser, Daniel <strong>and</strong> James Poterba, 2002, Do after-tax returns affect mutual fund <strong>in</strong>flows?<br />

Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ancial Economics 63, 381—414.<br />

Berk, Jonathan, <strong>and</strong> Richard Green, 2004, <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> <strong>Flows</strong> <strong>and</strong> Performance <strong>in</strong> Rational Markets,<br />

Journal of Political Economy 112, 1269-1295.<br />

Bris, Arturo, Husey<strong>in</strong> Gulen, Padma Kadiyala, <strong>and</strong> Raghavendra Rau, 2007, Good Stewards, Cheap<br />

Talkers, or Family Men? The Impact of <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> Closures on <strong>Fund</strong> Managers, <strong>Flows</strong>, Fees,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Performance, Review of F<strong>in</strong>ancial Studies 20, 953-982.<br />

Brown, Keith, W. Harlow, <strong>and</strong> Laura Starks, 1996, Of Tournaments <strong>and</strong> Temptations: An Analysis<br />

of <strong>Managerial</strong> <strong>Incentives</strong> <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> Industry, Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance 51, 85-110.<br />

Busse, Jeffrey, 2001, Another Look at <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> Tournaments, Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>and</strong> Quantitative<br />

Analysis 36, 53-73.<br />

Chen, Joseph, Harrison Hong, M<strong>in</strong>g Huang, <strong>and</strong> Jeffrey Kubik, 2004, Does <strong>Fund</strong> Size Erode <strong>Mutual</strong><br />

<strong>Fund</strong> Performance? The Role of Liquidity <strong>and</strong> Organization, American Economic Review, 94 (5),<br />

1276-1302.<br />

Chevalier, Judith, <strong>and</strong> Glenn Ellison, 1997, Risk Tak<strong>in</strong>g by <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong>s as a Response to <strong>Incentives</strong>,<br />

Journal of Political Economy 105, 1167-1200.<br />

Clements, Jonathan, Investors Flock to Low-Cost <strong>Fund</strong>s,”18 July 2007, The Wall Street Journal.<br />

Cooper, Mike, Husey<strong>in</strong> Gulen <strong>and</strong> Raghavendra Rau, 2005, Chang<strong>in</strong>g Names with Style: <strong>Mutual</strong><br />

<strong>Fund</strong> Name <strong>Changes</strong> <strong>and</strong> Their Effects on <strong>Fund</strong> <strong>Flows</strong>, Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance 60, 2825-2858.<br />

Del Guercio, Diane <strong>and</strong> Paula Tkac, 2002, The Determ<strong>in</strong>ants of the Flow of <strong>Fund</strong>s of Managed<br />

Portfolios: <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong>s versus Pension <strong>Fund</strong>s, Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>and</strong> Quantitative Analysis 37<br />

(4), 523-557.<br />

Elton, Edw<strong>in</strong>, Mart<strong>in</strong> J. Gruber, <strong>and</strong> Jeffrey Busse, 2004, Are Investors Rational? Choices Among<br />

Index <strong>Fund</strong>s, Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance 59 (1), 261-288.<br />

Elton, Edw<strong>in</strong>, Mart<strong>in</strong> J. Gruber, Christopher Blake, <strong>and</strong> Sadi Ozelge, 2009, The Effect of the<br />

Frequency of Hold<strong>in</strong>gs Data on Conclusions About <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> Management Behavior, work<strong>in</strong>g<br />

paper.<br />

Goetzmann, William <strong>and</strong> Massimo Massa, 2003, Index <strong>Fund</strong>s <strong>and</strong> Stock Market Growth, Journal<br />

of Bus<strong>in</strong>ess 76 (1), 1-28.<br />

Goetzmann, William <strong>and</strong> Nadav Peles, 1996, Cognitive Dissonance <strong>and</strong> <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> Investors,<br />

Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ancial Research, 20(2), 145-158.<br />

Gruber, Mart<strong>in</strong>, 1996, Another puzzle: The Growth <strong>in</strong> Actively Managed <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong>s, Journal<br />

of F<strong>in</strong>ance, 51, 783—810.<br />

33


Huang, Jennifer, Clemens Sialm, <strong>and</strong> Hanjiang Zhang, 2009, Risk Shift<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> Performance,<br />

work<strong>in</strong>g paper.<br />

Hunag, Jennifer, Kelsey Wei, <strong>and</strong> Hong Yan, 2007, Participation Costs <strong>and</strong> the Sensitivity of <strong>Fund</strong><br />

<strong>Flows</strong> to Past Performance, Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance 62 (3), 1273-1311.<br />

Investment Company Institute, 2010 Fact Book, http://www.icifactbook.org/.<br />

Ippolito, Richard A., 1992, Consumer Reaction to Measures of Poor Quality: Evidence from the<br />

<strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> Industry, Journal of Law <strong>and</strong> Economics 35, 45-70.<br />

Ivkovich, Zoran <strong>and</strong> Scott Weisbenner, 2009, Individual Investor <strong>Mutual</strong>-<strong>Fund</strong> <strong>Flows</strong>, Journal of<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ancial Economics 92, 223-237.<br />

Kaplan, Steven <strong>and</strong> Anto<strong>in</strong>ette Schoar, 2005, Private Equity Performance: Returns, Persistence,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Capital <strong>Flows</strong>, Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance 60 (4), 1791-1823.<br />

Kim, M<strong>in</strong>, 2010, Information Asymmetry <strong>and</strong> <strong>Incentives</strong> for Active Management, work<strong>in</strong>g paper.<br />

Koski, Jennifer <strong>and</strong> Jeffrey Pontiff, 1999, How Are Derivatives Used? Evidence from the <strong>Mutual</strong><br />

<strong>Fund</strong> Industry, Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance 54 (2), 791-816.<br />

Kostovetsky, Leonard, 2008, Bra<strong>in</strong> Dra<strong>in</strong>: Are <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong>s Los<strong>in</strong>g Their Best M<strong>in</strong>ds? work<strong>in</strong>g<br />

paper.<br />

Johnson, Woodrow, 2007, Who Monitors the <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> Manager, New or Old Shareholders?<br />

work<strong>in</strong>g paper.<br />

Lynch, Anthony, <strong>and</strong> David Musto, 2003, How Investors Interpret Past <strong>Fund</strong> Returns, Journal of.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ance 58 (5), 2033-2058.<br />

Massa, Massimo, Jonathan Reuter, <strong>and</strong> Eric Zitzewitz, 2009, When Should Firms Share Credit<br />

with Employees? Evidence from Anonymously Managed <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong>s, work<strong>in</strong>g paper.<br />

Olivier, Jacques <strong>and</strong> Anthony Tay, 2009, Time-Vary<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Incentives</strong> <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> Industry,<br />

work<strong>in</strong>g paper.<br />

O’Neal, Edward, 2004, Purchase <strong>and</strong> redemption patterns of U.S.equity mutual funds, F<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

Management 33, 63—90.<br />

Panageas, Stavros, <strong>and</strong> Mark Westerfield, 2009, High Water Marks: High Risk Appetites? Convex<br />

Compensation, Long Horizons, <strong>and</strong> Portfolio Choice, Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance 64 (1), 1-36.<br />

Rob<strong>in</strong>son, Peter, 1988, Root-N-Consistent Semiparametric Regression, Econometrica 56, 931-954.<br />

Sensoy, Berk, 2009, Evaluation <strong>and</strong> Self-Designated Benchmark Indexes <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> Industry,<br />

Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ancial Economics 92 (1), 25-39.<br />

Sigurdsson Kari, 2005, Why has the Flow-Performance Relationship <strong>in</strong> the U.S. <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong><br />

Industry become more l<strong>in</strong>ear?, London School of Bus<strong>in</strong>ess work<strong>in</strong>g paper.<br />

Sirri, Erik, <strong>and</strong> Peter Tufano, 1998, Costly Search <strong>and</strong> <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> <strong>Flows</strong>, Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance 53,<br />

1589-1622.<br />

34


Starks, Laura, 1987, Performance Incentive Fees: An Agency Theoretic Approach. Journal of<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>and</strong> Quantitative Analysis 22 (1), 17-32.<br />

Wang, Xiaolu, 2009, On Time Vary<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Mutual</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> Performance, work<strong>in</strong>g paper.<br />

Zheng, Lu, 1999, Is money smart? A study of mutual fund <strong>in</strong>vestors’fund selection ability, Journal<br />

of F<strong>in</strong>ance, 54, 901—933.<br />

35


Table I. Descriptive statistics<br />

Sample is U.S. mutual funds whose objectives are outperform<strong>in</strong>g market <strong>in</strong>dexes as stated <strong>in</strong> their prospectuses (non<strong>in</strong>dex funds)<br />

<strong>and</strong> which meet sampl<strong>in</strong>g criteria described <strong>in</strong> the paper (e.g., exclud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds, <strong>in</strong>ternational funds, funds closed to <strong>in</strong>vestors<br />

<strong>and</strong> small funds). Net ‡ow is changes <strong>in</strong> total net assets (TNA) exclud<strong>in</strong>g capital ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>and</strong> dividends, divided by TNA at the<br />

beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the period. Performance of a fund is its annual return m<strong>in</strong>us benchmark return. The benchmark return is return on the<br />

CRSP value weighted <strong>in</strong>dex (CRSP VW), return on the S&P500 <strong>in</strong>dex (SP500), return on the benchmark <strong>in</strong>dex designated by the<br />

fund (benchmark <strong>in</strong>dex), <strong>and</strong> the average return of the funds <strong>in</strong> the same style category as de…ned by the Morn<strong>in</strong>gstar (style return).<br />

Style return <strong>in</strong>cludes returns on <strong>in</strong>dex funds but exclude sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds. All returns are net of expense ratios<br />

but before load fees. Log age is the natural logarithm (log) of the months s<strong>in</strong>ce the <strong>in</strong>ception date of fund (age). Log size is the log<br />

of TNA of a fund divided by the average TNA of sample funds (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex funds but exclud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational<br />

funds). Expense ratio does not <strong>in</strong>clude load fees. Volatility is the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of monthly return of fund over the last two<br />

years. Industry ‡ow represents net ‡ows to all equity mutual funds <strong>in</strong> the CRSP database (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational<br />

funds). Style ‡ow is net ‡ows to the funds <strong>in</strong> each of 9 styles (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex funds but exclud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational<br />

funds). CRSP VW returns <strong>and</strong> volatility is the mean <strong>and</strong> the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of daily returns on the CRSP VW respectively<br />

(annualized). All variables are measured over a year at the end of December except expense ratios, which are over funds’…scal years.<br />

<strong>Fund</strong>s are aggregated across share classes, exclud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutional shares. Di¤ represents the t-statistics for equal means between the<br />

two periods, adjusted for correlations among funds <strong>and</strong> autocorrelations over time.<br />

1983-2008 1983-1999 2000-2008 Di¤<br />

variable mean median std mean median std mean median std mean<br />

‡ow (t) 0.105 -0.029 0.539 0.129 -0.009 0.539 0.090 -0.040 0.538 (-1.30)<br />

performance (t-1)<br />

return over CRSP VW 0.001 -0.015 0.134 -0.013 -0.018 0.111 0.010 -0.014 0.145 (0.95)<br />

return over SP500 0.004 -0.012 0.141 -0.032 -0.037 0.119 0.027 0.001 0.149 (1.98)<br />

return over benchmark 0.001 -0.011 0.120 -0.013 -0.020 0.107 0.010 -0.007 0.127 (1.07)<br />

return over style return 0.005 0.000 0.106 -0.002 -0.002 0.083 0.010 0.001 0.118 (1.97)<br />

log age (t-1) 4.859 4.762 0.766 4.966 4.875 0.849 4.793 4.710 0.702 (-3.01)<br />

age <strong>in</strong> years (t-1) 14.831 9.750 13.958 17.192 10.917 15.482 13.366 9.250 12.704 (-4.55)<br />

36


(Table I cont<strong>in</strong>ued)<br />

1983-2008 1983-1999 2000-2008 Di¤<br />

variable mean median std mean median std mean median std mean<br />

size (t-1) 0.958 0.914 1.630 1.023 0.964 1.520 0.918 0.879 1.694 (-1.04)<br />

TNA <strong>in</strong> billions (t) 1.285 0.274 4.619 1.026 0.242 3.035 1.445 0.298 5.366 (3.88)<br />

expense ratio (t-1) 0.012 0.012 0.004 0.012 0.011 0.005 0.012 0.012 0.004 (1.82)<br />

volatility (t-1) 0.043 0.038 0.022 0.044 0.040 0.020 0.043 0.037 0.023 (-0.11)<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry ‡ow (t) 0.070 0.060 0.076 0.087 0.082 0.086 0.037 0.040 0.041 (-2.00)<br />

style ‡ow (t) 0.081 0.061 0.112 0.098 0.097 0.128 0.047 0.022 0.066 (-1.51)<br />

CRSP VW returns (t-1) 0.132 0.155 0.138 0.166 0.198 0.110 0.067 0.084 0.167 (-1.63)<br />

CRSP VW volatility (t-1) 0.144 0.127 0.055 0.130 0.121 0.050 0.169 0.160 0.057 (1.75)<br />

observations (funds) 17679 (2264) 6771 (1011) 10908 (2048)<br />

37


Table II. Estimations for control variables <strong>in</strong> kernel regressions<br />

The dependent variable of the semi-nonparametric regressions is annual net ‡ows <strong>in</strong> the year t <strong>and</strong> the<br />

<strong>in</strong>dependent variables are listed <strong>in</strong> the …rst column. Numbers for each <strong>in</strong>dependent variable are estimates <strong>and</strong><br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard errors, clustered by year <strong>and</strong> fund. Regressions are di¤erent depend<strong>in</strong>g on performance measures,<br />

as described <strong>in</strong> the …rst row. Style returns are the average returns of the funds <strong>in</strong> the same style categories as<br />

de…ned by the Morn<strong>in</strong>gstar. Log age is the natural logarithm (log) of the months s<strong>in</strong>ce the <strong>in</strong>ception date of<br />

the fund. Log size is the log of TNA of the fund divided by the average TNA of sample funds (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex<br />

funds but exclud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds). Expense ratio does not <strong>in</strong>clude load fees. Volatility<br />

is the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of monthly return of the fund over the last two years. Industry ‡ow represents<br />

net ‡ows to all equity mutual funds <strong>in</strong> the CRSP database (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds).<br />

Style ‡ow is net ‡ows to the funds <strong>in</strong> each of 9 styles (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex funds but exclud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>ternational funds). All variables are measured over a year at the end of December except expense ratios,<br />

which are over the fund’…scal year. The numbers of observations are 6,771 <strong>and</strong> 10,908 from 1983 to 2008<br />

<strong>and</strong> from 2000 to 2008 respectively. <strong>Fund</strong>s are aggregated across share classes, exclud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutional share<br />

classes.<br />

performance: return over CRSP VW return over style return<br />

1983-1999 2000-2008 1983-1999 2000-2008<br />

performance (t) 0.800 1.041 0.835 1.265<br />

(0.138) (0.119) (0.191) (0.170)<br />

performance (t-2) 0.456 0.287 0.581 0.346<br />

(0.133) (0.106) (0.139) (0.117)<br />

log age (t-1) -0.032 -0.027 -0.017 -0.032<br />

(0.009) (0.008) (0.009) (0.009)<br />

log size (t-1) -0.026 -0.039 -0.029 -0.040<br />

(0.005) (0.006) (0.005) (0.005)<br />

expense ratio (t-1) 4.532 -2.747 3.404 -1.980<br />

(1.499) (1.338) (1.562) (1.372)<br />

volatility (t-1) -2.163 0.460 -0.701 -0.118<br />

(0.535) (0.745) (0.544) (0.448)<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry ‡ow (t) 0.389 -0.028 0.146 0.129<br />

(0.199) (0.477) (0.174) (0.358)<br />

style ‡ow (t) 0.278 0.049 0.597 0.889<br />

(0.079) (0.144) (0.063) (0.063)<br />

‡ow (t-1) 0.301 0.230 0.282 0.209<br />

(0.030) (0.038) (0.027) (0.035)<br />

38


Table III. OLS regression of net ‡ows<br />

The dependent variable of the ord<strong>in</strong>ary least square regressions is annual net fund ‡ows <strong>in</strong> the year<br />

t <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dependent variables are listed <strong>in</strong> the …rst column. Numbers for each <strong>in</strong>dependent variable are<br />

estimates, st<strong>and</strong>ard errors, <strong>and</strong> p-values respectively. The st<strong>and</strong>ard errors are clustered by year <strong>and</strong> fund.<br />

Regressions are di¤erent depend<strong>in</strong>g on the performance measures, as described <strong>in</strong> the …rst row. See Table I<br />

for the variable description. The numbers of observations are 6,771 <strong>and</strong> 10,908 from 1983 to 2008 <strong>and</strong> from<br />

2000 to 2008 respectively. <strong>Fund</strong>s are aggregated across share classes, exclud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutional share classes.<br />

The columns Di¤ show the test results for equal coe¢ cients on the <strong>in</strong>dividual variables. The values represent<br />

the coe¢ cients on the <strong>in</strong>teraction terms between the variables <strong>and</strong> the second period dummy, their st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

errors <strong>and</strong> p-values respectively (st<strong>and</strong>ard errors are clustered by year <strong>and</strong> fund). P-values are the Chow-test<br />

p-values for jo<strong>in</strong>t tests of equal coe¢ cients on the variables.<br />

return over CRSP VW return over style returns<br />

1983-1999 2000-2008 Di¤ 1983-1999 2000-2008 Di¤<br />

<strong>in</strong>tercept 0.489 0.511 -0.060 0.281 0.484 -0.013<br />

(0.089) (0.106) (0.029) (0.082) (0.100) (0.019)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.036) (0.001) (0.000) (0.501)<br />

performance (t-1) 1.507 0.933 -0.664 1.798 1.214 -0.678<br />

(0.186) (0.209) (0.232) (0.193) (0.239) (0.310)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.004) (0.000) (0.000) (0.029)<br />

squared performance 0.662 -0.323 -1.469 2.264 -0.409 -3.037<br />

(t-1) (0.643) (0.088) (0.314) (0.919) (0.124) (0.757)<br />

(0.303) (0.000) (0.000) (0.014) (0.001) (0.000)<br />

performance (t) 0.731 0.978 0.244 0.750 1.262 0.511<br />

(0.123) (0.133) (0.190) (0.174) (0.177) (0.247)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.199) (0.000) (0.000) (0.039)<br />

performance (t-2) 0.905 0.494 -0.460 1.194 0.618 -0.660<br />

(0.143) (0.135) (0.208) (0.135) (0.160) (0.198)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.028) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001)<br />

log age (t-1) -0.080 -0.075 0.005 -0.058 -0.076 -0.017<br />

(0.013) (0.016) (0.020) (0.012) (0.016) (0.021)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.813) (0.000) (0.000) (0.424)<br />

log size (t-1) -0.008 -0.032 -0.014 -0.014 -0.033 -0.018<br />

(0.005) (0.005) (0.008) (0.004) (0.005) (0.007)<br />

(0.152) (0.000) (0.075) (0.001) (0.000) (0.019)<br />

39


(Table III cont<strong>in</strong>ued)<br />

return over CRSP VW return over style returns<br />

1983-1999 2000-2008 Di¤ 1983-1999 2000-2008 Di¤<br />

expense ratio (t-1) 8.094 -4.073 -9.305 6.017 -2.844 -6.547<br />

(2.021) (1.864) (2.653) (1.942) (1.570) (2.404)<br />

(0.000) (0.029) (0.000) (0.002) (0.070) (0.007)<br />

volatility (t-1) -2.028 -0.103 0.830 -0.462 -0.135 -0.515<br />

(0.532) (0.897) (1.080) (0.479) (0.700) (0.813)<br />

(0.000) (0.909) (0.442) (0.335) (0.847) (0.527)<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry ‡ow (t) 0.441 0.232 0.009 0.236 0.185 -0.045<br />

(0.206) (0.502) (0.525) (0.153) (0.307) (0.323)<br />

(0.032) (0.644) (0.987) (0.122) (0.547) (0.888)<br />

style ‡ow (t) 0.489 0.014 -0.459 0.709 0.982 0.246<br />

(0.089) (0.163) (0.241) (0.093) (0.065) (0.116)<br />

(0.000) (0.930) (0.057) (0.000) (0.000) (0.034)<br />

Adjusted R 2 (p-values) 0.214 0.126 (0.000) 0.228 0.150 (0.000)<br />

40


Table IV. Determ<strong>in</strong>ants of ‡ow-performance sensitivity<br />

The dependent variable is annual net fund ‡ows <strong>in</strong> the year t <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dependent variables are listed<br />

<strong>in</strong> the …rst column. Numbers for each <strong>in</strong>dependent variable are estimates, st<strong>and</strong>ard errors, <strong>and</strong> p-values<br />

respectively. The st<strong>and</strong>ard errors are clustered by year <strong>and</strong> fund. Regressions are di¤erent depend<strong>in</strong>g on<br />

performance measures. Style returns are the average returns of the funds <strong>in</strong> the same style category as<br />

de…ned by the Morn<strong>in</strong>gstar. Squared performance is square of performance. This variable has <strong>in</strong>teraction<br />

terms with …ve condition<strong>in</strong>g variables. Market ret state is -1, 0, <strong>and</strong> +1 when the mean of daily returns<br />

on the CRSP VW <strong>in</strong>dex over the year is <strong>in</strong> the low, middle, <strong>and</strong> high group respectively. Similarly, market<br />

vol state is -1 (low volatility), 0 (medium), <strong>and</strong> +1 (high) accord<strong>in</strong>g to the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of daily<br />

returns; <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry ‡ow state is equal to -1 (low), 0 (medium), <strong>and</strong> +1 (high dem<strong>and</strong>), depend<strong>in</strong>g on<br />

net ‡ows to all equity mutual funds <strong>in</strong> the CRSP database (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds).<br />

Performance dispersion is the residual obta<strong>in</strong>ed from the regressions of the cross-sectional st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation<br />

of performance on the mean <strong>and</strong> the volatility of the daily CRSP VW returns. The second period is one if<br />

the year is between 2000 <strong>and</strong> 2008 <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. The expense ratio does not <strong>in</strong>clude load fees. The<br />

variables not presented <strong>in</strong> the table <strong>in</strong>clude performance (t); performance (t-2); log age (t-1; the log of the<br />

months s<strong>in</strong>ce the <strong>in</strong>ception date of fund); log size (t-1; the log of TNA of a fund divided by the average<br />

TNA of sample funds, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex funds); volatility (t-1; the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of monthly return of<br />

fund over the last two years); <strong>in</strong>dustry ‡ow (t); <strong>and</strong> style ‡ow (t; net ‡ows to the funds <strong>in</strong> each of 9 styles,<br />

<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex funds). All variables are measured over a year at the end of December except expense ratios,<br />

which are over funds’…scal years. The number of observations is 17,679 over 1983 to 2008. <strong>Fund</strong> variables<br />

are aggregated across share classes, exclud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutional share classes.<br />

41


(A) performance: excess return over CRSP VW<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)<br />

performance (t-1) 1.064 0.822 0.829 0.844 0.897 0.920 0.907<br />

(0.165) (0.151) (0.149) (0.151) (0.140) (0.133) (0.131)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

squared performance (t-1) -0.370 -0.384 0.647 0.761 0.697 0.628 0.966<br />

(0.079) (0.066) (0.312) (0.620) (0.638) (0.566) (0.572)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.038) (0.220) (0.274) (0.267) (0.092)<br />

*market ret state (t-1) -0.304 -0.717 -0.604 -0.728<br />

(0.482) (0.532) (0.360) (0.416)<br />

(0.528) (0.178) (0.094) (0.081)<br />

*market vol state (t-1) -0.879 -1.564 -0.951 -0.375<br />

(0.440) (0.564) (0.557) (0.662)<br />

(0.046) (0.006) (0.088) (0.571)<br />

*performance dispersion 6.536 8.773 9.370<br />

(t-1) (2.573) (0.909) (0.896)<br />

(0.011) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

*<strong>in</strong>dustry ‡ow state (t) 1.083 0.736<br />

(0.363) (0.389)<br />

(0.003) (0.059)<br />

*second period (t) -1.056 -1.238<br />

(0.307) (0.699)<br />

(0.001) (0.077)<br />

expense ratio (t-1) 0.032 -0.324 1.583 1.915 2.119 2.094 1.827<br />

(2.034) (1.567) (2.153) (2.197) (2.196) (2.252) (2.268)<br />

(0.987) (0.836) (0.463) (0.384) (0.335) (0.353) (0.420)<br />

*second period (t) -3.017 -3.883 -3.854 -3.709 -2.982<br />

(2.160) (2.181) (2.053) (2.176) (2.144)<br />

(0.163) (0.075) (0.061) (0.089) (0.165)<br />

‡ow (t-1) 0.260 0.257 0.257 0.259 0.259 0.259<br />

(0.028) (0.028) (0.028) (0.028) (0.028) (0.028)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

Adjusted R squared 0.147 0.225 0.228 0.228 0.230 0.232 0.232<br />

42


(Table IV cont<strong>in</strong>ued)<br />

(B) performance: excess return over style return<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)<br />

performance (t-1) 1.401 1.119 1.118 1.127 1.142 1.158 1.158<br />

(0.193) (0.159) (0.160) (0.168) (0.163) (0.160) (0.160)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

squared performance (t-1) -0.508 -0.470 1.631 2.878 2.834 2.755 2.995<br />

(0.095) (0.086) (0.698) (0.810) (0.761) (0.769) (1.024)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.020) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.004)<br />

*market ret state (t-1) -0.659 -1.171 -1.102 -1.184<br />

(0.410) (0.525) (0.307) (0.360)<br />

(0.108) (0.026) (0.000) (0.001)<br />

*market vol state (t-1) -2.738 -3.451 -2.865 -2.571<br />

(0.861) (0.881) (0.891) (0.887)<br />

(0.002) (0.000) (0.001) (0.004)<br />

*performance dispersion 7.657 11.615 12.119<br />

(t-1) (3.889) (1.183) (1.092)<br />

(0.049) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

*<strong>in</strong>dustry ‡ow state (t) 1.254 1.091<br />

(0.462) (0.531)<br />

(0.007) (0.040)<br />

*second period (t) -2.125 -0.700<br />

(0.704) (1.125)<br />

(0.003) (0.534)<br />

expense ratio (t-1) 0.388 -0.062 -0.528 -0.671 -0.546 -0.533 -0.617<br />

(1.705) (1.325) (1.806) (1.854) (1.827) (1.849) (1.852)<br />

(0.820) (0.963) (0.770) (0.718) (0.765) (0.773) (0.739)<br />

*second period (t) 0.432 -0.165 -0.215 -0.155 0.052<br />

(1.648) (1.584) (1.548) (1.597) (1.535)<br />

(0.794) (0.917) (0.889) (0.923) (0.973)<br />

‡ow (t-1) 0.249 0.246 0.244 0.246 0.247 0.247<br />

(0.027) (0.027) (0.027) (0.027) (0.027) (0.027)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

Adjusted R squared 0.169 0.240 0.242 0.245 0.246 0.247 0.247<br />

43


Table V. Descriptive statistics for risk shift measures<br />

Descriptive statistics for four risk-shift measures: total risk (Dec-Sep), idiosyncratic risk (Dec-Sep), systematic risk (Dec-Sep),<br />

<strong>and</strong> Risk-shift. Total risk of a fund <strong>in</strong> a given month <strong>in</strong> year t is the annualized st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of daily excess returns over the<br />

CRSP VW <strong>in</strong>dex of a portfolio that holds the same stocks <strong>in</strong> the fund at the end of the month. Daily returns are over the prior<br />

calendar year (i.e., year t-1). Total risk (Dec-Sep) is total risk <strong>in</strong> December m<strong>in</strong>us total risk <strong>in</strong> September. Idiosyncratic risk of a fund<br />

<strong>in</strong> a given month is the annualized st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of unexpected daily returns of a portfolio, de…ned as returns on the portfolio<br />

m<strong>in</strong>us the portfolio beta times returns on the CRSP VW. The portfolio beta is weighted average of betas of the stocks, which are<br />

the slope estimates when regress<strong>in</strong>g the stock’s daily returns on the CRSP VW returns over the prior calendar year. Systematic risk<br />

(Dec-Sep) <strong>in</strong> year t is the di¤erence between the absolute value of beta <strong>in</strong> December m<strong>in</strong>us one <strong>and</strong> the absolute value of beta <strong>in</strong><br />

September m<strong>in</strong>us one. Hypothetical volatility is the annualized st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of monthly return on a portfolio over the prior<br />

36 months that holds the same stocks at the end of the month. Actual volatility is the annualized st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of the fund’s<br />

actual returns over the prior 36 months. The sample <strong>in</strong>cludes only the fund whose correspond<strong>in</strong>g portfolios have at least 80n% of the<br />

fund TNAs. Age is the number of months s<strong>in</strong>ce the <strong>in</strong>ception date of a fund. The sample period is from 1983 to 2008. Di¤represents<br />

the t-statistics for equal means between the two periods, adjusted for correlations among funds <strong>and</strong> autocorrelations.<br />

1983-2008 1983-1999 2000-2008 Di¤<br />

variable mean median std mean median std mean median std mean<br />

total risk (Dec - Sep) (%) -0.055 -0.012 0.807 -0.038 -0.003 0.950 -0.060 -0.014 0.759 (-0.18)<br />

idiosyncratic risk (Dec-Sep) (%) -0.039 -0.008 0.693 -0.048 -0.006 0.881 -0.036 -0.009 0.627 (0.12)<br />

systematic risk (Dec-Sep) (%) -0.339 -0.095 4.808 -0.360 0.055 5.647 -0.332 -0.118 4.529 (0.05)<br />

total risk (Sep) 0.083 0.071 0.050 0.087 0.077 0.041 0.082 0.069 0.052 (-0.38)<br />

idiosyncratic risk (Sep) 0.075 0.065 0.042 0.080 0.070 0.038 0.073 0.063 0.043 (-0.71)<br />

systematic risk (Sep) 0.194 0.141 0.177 0.224 0.183 0.178 0.185 0.128 0.175 (-1.44)<br />

equity <strong>in</strong> billion 1.249 0.257 4.000 0.543 0.127 1.738 1.459 0.323 4.433 (4.63)<br />

age <strong>in</strong> years 16.461 11.667 14.123 12.636 6.667 14.008 17.597 12.667 13.957 (4.95)<br />

return over CRSP VW (Sep) 0.005 -0.006 0.094 -0.003 -0.008 0.101 0.007 -0.006 0.092 (0.83)<br />

number of observations 9644 2207 7437<br />

44


(Table V cont<strong>in</strong>ued)<br />

1983-2008 1983-1999 2000-2008 Di¤<br />

variable mean median std mean median std mean median std mean<br />

hypothetical - actual volatility (Dec) 0.004 0.004 0.038 0.020 0.016 0.033 0.001 0.002 0.038 (-2.24)<br />

hypothetical volatility (Dec) 0.221 0.213 0.085 0.244 0.242 0.079 0.217 0.207 0.085 (-0.48)<br />

actual volatility (Dec) 0.217 0.209 0.086 0.224 0.222 0.072 0.216 0.206 0.089 (-0.08)<br />

equity <strong>in</strong> billion 1.486 0.315 4.686 0.855 0.155 3.336 1.580 0.350 4.848 (2.87)<br />

age <strong>in</strong> years 18.169 13.667 14.451 15.789 9.667 15.405 18.525 13.667 14.269 (2.15)<br />

return over CRSP VW (Sep) -0.002 -0.010 0.084 -0.008 -0.008 0.094 -0.001 -0.010 0.082 (0.98)<br />

number of observations 6723 952 5771<br />

45


Table VI. OLS regressions for risk shift measures by Chevalier <strong>and</strong> Ellison (1997)<br />

The dependent variables are risk-shift measures as listed <strong>in</strong> the column header <strong>and</strong> described <strong>in</strong> the below. The <strong>in</strong>dependent<br />

variables are listed <strong>in</strong> the …rst column. The numbers for each <strong>in</strong>dependent variable are estimates, st<strong>and</strong>ard errors, <strong>and</strong> p-values<br />

respectively. The regressions <strong>in</strong>clude year dummy, <strong>and</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard errors are clustered by fund. Second period is a dummy variable that<br />

takes one if the year is between 2000 <strong>and</strong> 2008 <strong>and</strong> zero if the year is between 1983 <strong>and</strong> 1999. Risk (Sep) is total risk, idiosyncratic<br />

risk <strong>and</strong> systematic risk at the end of September respectively. Market return (Sep) <strong>and</strong> market volatility (Sep) are the mean <strong>and</strong><br />

the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of daily returns on the CRSP VW <strong>in</strong>dex from January to September (annualized) respectively. Log size is<br />

the natural logarithm (log) of the value of the hypothetical portfolio constructed as described <strong>in</strong> the below. Log age is the log of<br />

months s<strong>in</strong>ce the <strong>in</strong>ception date. Performance (Sep) is excess returns on funds over the CRSP value-weighted <strong>in</strong>dex from January<br />

to September. Performance dispersion (Sep) is the residual of the cross-sectional st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of performance of sample funds<br />

from January to September after regress<strong>in</strong>g it on market return (Sep) <strong>and</strong> market volatility (Sep). The dependent variables are as<br />

follows. Total risk of a fund <strong>in</strong> a given month <strong>in</strong> year t is the annualized st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of daily excess returns over the CRSP<br />

value-weighted <strong>in</strong>dex (CRSP VW) of the hypothetical portfolio that holds the same stocks <strong>in</strong> the fund at the end of that month.<br />

Daily returns are over the prior calendar year (i.e., year t-1). Idiosyncratic risk of a fund <strong>in</strong> a given month is the annualized st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

deviation of unexpected daily returns of the hypothetical portfolio, de…ned as returns on the portfolio m<strong>in</strong>us the portfolio beta times<br />

returns on the CRSP VW. The portfolio beta is weighted average of betas of the stocks, which are the slope estimates when regress<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the stock’s daily returns on the CRSP VW returns over the prior calendar year. Systematic risk (Dec-Sep) <strong>in</strong> year t is the di¤erence<br />

between the absolute value of beta <strong>in</strong> December m<strong>in</strong>us one <strong>and</strong> the absolute value of beta <strong>in</strong> September m<strong>in</strong>us one. The sample<br />

period is from 1983 to 2008 <strong>and</strong> the numbers of observations is 9,644.<br />

total risk idiosyncratic risk systematic risk<br />

(1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3)<br />

<strong>in</strong>tercept -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 -0.020 -0.019 -0.019<br />

(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.016) (0.015) (0.015)<br />

(0.576) (0.659) (0.658) (0.683) (0.598) (0.605) (0.211) (0.205) (0.206)<br />

second period 0.001 0.001 0.000 0.000 0.026 0.025<br />

(0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.015) (0.015)<br />

(0.451) (0.549) (0.895) (0.816) (0.082) (0.088)<br />

46


(Table VI cont<strong>in</strong>ued)<br />

total risk idiosyncratic risk systematic risk<br />

(1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3)<br />

risk (Sep) -0.015 -0.015 -0.015 -0.018 -0.018 -0.018 -0.044 -0.043 -0.043<br />

(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

log size (Sep) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

(0.701) (0.756) (0.755) (0.985) (0.915) (0.924) (0.875) (0.983) (0.974)<br />

log age (Sep) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)<br />

(0.541) (0.476) (0.476) (0.829) (0.821) (0.820) (0.607) (0.505) (0.506)<br />

performance (Sep) -0.011 -0.004 -0.004 -0.010 -0.003 -0.004 -0.010 -0.005 0.001<br />

(0.003) (0.001) (0.003) (0.002) (0.001) (0.003) (0.014) (0.008) (0.016)<br />

(0.000) (0.013) (0.165) (0.000) (0.043) (0.156) (0.474) (0.520) (0.941)<br />

*market return (Sep) 0.002 0.003 -0.025 -0.022 0.255 0.240<br />

(0.013) (0.014) (0.012) (0.013) (0.071) (0.074)<br />

(0.895) (0.852) (0.032) (0.074) (0.000) (0.001)<br />

*market volatility (Sep) 0.024 0.024 -0.037 -0.040 0.895 0.907<br />

(0.036) (0.036) (0.034) (0.033) (0.203) (0.201)<br />

(0.500) (0.510) (0.266) (0.234) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

*performance dispersion (Sep) -0.310 -0.305 -0.252 -0.235 -1.037 -1.125<br />

(0.053) (0.060) (0.046) (0.051) (0.273) (0.326)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001)<br />

*second period 0.007 0.000 0.008 0.002 0.015 -0.009<br />

(0.003) (0.004) (0.003) (0.003) (0.016) (0.020)<br />

(0.011) (0.889) (0.001) (0.573) (0.345) (0.634)<br />

adjusted R squared 0.060 0.067 0.067 0.054 0.058 0.058 0.056 0.062 0.062<br />

47


Table VII. Determ<strong>in</strong>ants of ‡ow-performance (rank<strong>in</strong>g) sensitivity<br />

See Table 4 for details. The only di¤erence is performance, which is rank<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the ascend<strong>in</strong>g order<br />

based on annual returns m<strong>in</strong>us the CRSP value weighted <strong>in</strong>dex (CRSP), divided by the total number of<br />

funds <strong>in</strong> a given year. (The complete results are available upon request).<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)<br />

performance (t-1) 0.445 0.360 0.361 0.363 0.364 0.363 0.363<br />

(0.046) (0.043) (0.044) (0.044) (0.044) (0.044) (0.044)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

squared performance (t-1) 0.517 0.352 0.610 0.365 0.363 0.365 0.654<br />

(0.123) (0.119) (0.131) (0.122) (0.124) (0.109) (0.152)<br />

(0.000) (0.003) (0.000) (0.003) (0.003) (0.001) (0.000)<br />

*market ret state (t-1) -0.138 -0.167 -0.166 -0.233<br />

(0.143) (0.143) (0.126) (0.133)<br />

(0.336) (0.243) (0.185) (0.078)<br />

*market vol state (t-1) -0.103 -0.133 -0.125 -0.072<br />

(0.141) (0.135) (0.145) (0.131)<br />

(0.465) (0.325) (0.387) (0.583)<br />

*performance dispersion 2.429 2.937 3.280<br />

(t-1) (1.622) (1.420) (1.514)<br />

(0.134) (0.039) (0.030)<br />

*<strong>in</strong>dustry ‡ow state (t) 0.216 0.124<br />

(0.143) (0.126)<br />

(0.131) (0.323)<br />

*second period (t) -0.410 -0.479<br />

(0.187) (0.170)<br />

(0.028) (0.005)<br />

expense ratio (t-1) 0.772 0.300 -0.173 1.400 1.538 1.435 0.170<br />

(2.055) (1.558) (2.149) (1.972) (1.960) (1.981) (2.080)<br />

(0.707) (0.847) (0.936) (0.478) (0.433) (0.469) (0.935)<br />

*second period (t) 1.026 -1.716 -1.930 -1.685 0.642<br />

(2.014) (1.946) (1.808) (1.851) (1.995)<br />

(0.610) (0.378) (0.286) (0.363) (0.748)<br />

‡ow (t-1) 0.251 0.252 0.252 0.251 0.252 0.252<br />

(0.029) (0.029) (0.029) (0.029) (0.029) (0.029)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

Adjusted R squared 0.161 0.233 0.234 0.234 0.234 0.235 0.236<br />

48


Table VIII. Descriptive statistics for <strong>in</strong>dex funds<br />

The sample is U.S. mutual funds whose objectives are track<strong>in</strong>g market <strong>in</strong>dexes as stated <strong>in</strong> their prospectuses (<strong>in</strong>dex funds) <strong>and</strong><br />

which meet sampl<strong>in</strong>g criteria described <strong>in</strong> the paper (e.g., exclud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds, <strong>in</strong>ternational funds, funds closed to <strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>and</strong><br />

small funds). See Table I for the variable description.<br />

1983-2008 1983-1999 2000-2008 Di¤<br />

variable mean median std mean median std mean median std mean<br />

‡ow (t) 0.125 0.033 0.449 0.298 0.202 0.430 0.077 0.009 0.443 (-4.03)<br />

performance (t-1)<br />

return over CRSP VW -0.001 -0.017 0.089 0.013 0.013 0.080 -0.005 -0.026 0.091 (-0.67)<br />

return over SP500 0.008 -0.006 0.097 -0.012 -0.002 0.082 0.013 -0.009 0.100 (0.81)<br />

return over benchmark 0.001 -0.006 0.074 0.006 0.001 0.056 0.000 -0.014 0.078 (-0.23)<br />

return over style return 0.004 0.002 0.057 0.023 0.018 0.046 -0.001 0.000 0.059 (-1.78)<br />

log age (t-1) 4.528 4.477 0.546 4.399 4.277 0.576 4.563 4.543 0.532 (1.42)<br />

age <strong>in</strong> years (t-1) 9.074 7.333 6.067 8.317 6.000 6.888 9.281 7.833 5.811 (0.73)<br />

size (t-1) 1.533 1.553 1.770 1.592 1.583 1.593 1.517 1.532 1.816 (-0.27)<br />

TNA <strong>in</strong> billions (t) 3.451 0.590 11.815 3.010 0.636 9.594 3.571 0.569 12.353 (2.83)<br />

expense ratio (t-1) 0.005 0.004 0.004 0.004 0.004 0.003 0.005 0.004 0.004 (1.19)<br />

volatility (t-1) 0.038 0.033 0.018 0.040 0.036 0.018 0.037 0.033 0.018 (-0.35)<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry ‡ow (t) 0.070 0.060 0.076 0.087 0.082 0.086 0.037 0.040 0.041 (-2.00)<br />

style ‡ow (t) 0.081 0.061 0.112 0.098 0.097 0.128 0.047 0.022 0.066 (-1.51)<br />

CRSP VW returns (t-1) 0.132 0.155 0.138 0.166 0.198 0.110 0.067 0.084 0.167 (-1.63)<br />

CRSP VW volatility (t-1) 0.144 0.127 0.055 0.130 0.121 0.050 0.169 0.160 0.057 (1.75)<br />

observations (funds) 1172 (185) 251 (52) 921 (181)<br />

49


Table IX. Determ<strong>in</strong>ants of ‡ow-performance sensitivity for <strong>in</strong>dex funds<br />

The dependent variable of ord<strong>in</strong>ary least square regressions is annual net ‡ows for <strong>in</strong>dex funds <strong>in</strong> the<br />

year t <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dependent variables are listed <strong>in</strong> the …rst column. Numbers for each <strong>in</strong>dependent variable are<br />

estimates, st<strong>and</strong>ard errors (clustered by year <strong>and</strong> fund), <strong>and</strong> p-values respectively. Regressions are di¤erent<br />

depend<strong>in</strong>g on performance measures. See Table IV for the variable description. (The complete results,<br />

<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g for other performance measures, are available upon request.)<br />

(A) performance: excess return over CRSP VW<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)<br />

performance (t-1) 0.149 0.094 0.065 0.070 0.045 0.021 -0.002<br />

(0.163) (0.154) (0.140) (0.138) (0.139) (0.146) (0.153)<br />

(0.363) (0.542) (0.640) (0.615) (0.746) (0.886) (0.992)<br />

squared performance (t-1) 0.380 0.289 -2.195 -3.516 -2.894 -2.999 -0.276<br />

(0.000) (0.128) (2.193) (2.161) (2.623) (2.633) (3.692)<br />

(0.000) (0.024) (0.317) (0.104) (0.270) (0.255) (0.940)<br />

*market ret state (t-1) -0.443 0.248 0.398 0.574<br />

(0.309) (0.798) (0.792) (0.804)<br />

(0.152) (0.756) (0.615) (0.475)<br />

*market vol state (t-1) 4.373 4.537 4.149 5.872<br />

(2.235) (2.434) (2.507) (2.785)<br />

(0.051) (0.063) (0.098) (0.035)<br />

*performance dispersion -36.739 -54.999 -95.602<br />

(t-1) (30.460) (34.576) (43.990)<br />

(0.228) (0.112) (0.030)<br />

*<strong>in</strong>dustry ‡ow state (t) -1.129 -3.244<br />

(0.750) (1.615)<br />

(0.133) (0.045)<br />

*second period (t) 2.655 -5.158<br />

(2.253) (3.986)<br />

(0.239) (0.196)<br />

expense ratio (t-1) -19.940 -19.277 -12.251 -11.722 -13.653 -13.662 -14.845<br />

(6.004) (5.716) (7.779) (8.010) (8.267) (8.305) (7.807)<br />

(0.001) (0.001) (0.116) (0.144) (0.099) (0.100) (0.058)<br />

*second period (t) -9.010 -9.224 -7.933 -8.226 -6.350<br />

(7.743) (8.033) (7.834) (7.883) (7.645)<br />

(0.245) (0.251) (0.311) (0.297) (0.406)<br />

‡ow (t-1) 0.051 0.051 0.053 0.052 0.051 0.048<br />

(0.052) (0.052) (0.052) (0.052) (0.052) (0.052)<br />

(0.329) (0.326) (0.312) (0.316) (0.321) (0.351)<br />

Adjusted R squared 0.090 0.092 0.093 0.094 0.094 0.094 0.094<br />

50


(Table IX cont<strong>in</strong>ued.)<br />

(B) performance: excess return over style return<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)<br />

performance (t-1) 0.462 0.419 0.442 0.709 0.652 0.543 0.620<br />

(0.183) (0.169) (0.161) (0.240) (0.230) (0.233) (0.257)<br />

(0.012) (0.013) (0.006) (0.003) (0.005) (0.020) (0.016)<br />

squared performance (t-1) 0.202 0.092 -6.000 -1.384 0.161 0.138 -2.799<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (7.318) (4.275) (4.535) (4.521) (7.148)<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.412) (0.746) (0.972) (0.976) (0.695)<br />

*market ret state (t-1) -1.549 -0.019 0.533 0.410<br />

(0.787) (1.278) (1.226) (1.159)<br />

(0.049) (0.988) (0.664) (0.724)<br />

*market vol state (t-1) 2.411 3.735 3.169 1.616<br />

(4.156) (4.096) (4.089) (4.590)<br />

(0.562) (0.362) (0.438) (0.725)<br />

*performance dispersion -103.642 -181.112 -161.312<br />

(t-1) (62.091) (77.728) (81.924)<br />

(0.095) (0.020) (0.049)<br />

*<strong>in</strong>dustry ‡ow state (t) -3.470 -2.354<br />

(1.600) (2.516)<br />

(0.030) (0.350)<br />

*second period (t) 6.167 4.805<br />

(7.308) (8.410)<br />

(0.399) (0.568)<br />

expense ratio (t-1) -19.843 -19.288 -15.830 -15.919 -17.200 -17.783 -17.367<br />

(6.278) (6.071) (7.378) (7.352) (7.355) (7.219) (7.231)<br />

(0.002) (0.002) (0.032) (0.031) (0.020) (0.014) (0.016)<br />

*second period (t) -4.596 -4.031 -2.854 -2.325 -3.190<br />

(7.308) (6.971) (6.659) (6.790) (7.348)<br />

(0.530) (0.563) (0.668) (0.732) (0.664)<br />

‡ow (t-1) 0.048 0.047 0.047 0.046 0.046 0.045<br />

(0.050) (0.050) (0.050) (0.049) (0.049) (0.049)<br />

(0.336) (0.343) (0.345) (0.350) (0.354) (0.356)<br />

Adjusted R squared 0.093 0.095 0.094 0.095 0.095 0.096 0.095<br />

51


Figure II. Sample composition<br />

Sample is U.S. non<strong>in</strong>dex mutual funds that meet sampl<strong>in</strong>g criteria described <strong>in</strong> the paper. Panel (A)<br />

shows the proportion of small (less than the median fund size of $0.3 billion) <strong>and</strong> large funds, <strong>and</strong> (B) shows<br />

the proportion of young (younger than the median fund age of 10 years) <strong>and</strong> old funds. Panel (C) shows the<br />

composition of fund styles (size <strong>and</strong> value characteristics accord<strong>in</strong>g to Morn<strong>in</strong>gstar).<br />

%<br />

%<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

1983<br />

1983<br />

1984<br />

1984<br />

1985<br />

1985<br />

1986<br />

1986<br />

1987<br />

1987<br />

1988<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1992<br />

(A) <strong>Fund</strong> size<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

Small<br />

(< $0.3B)<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

(B) <strong>Fund</strong> age<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1997<br />

Young<br />

(< 10yrs)<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

Old<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2001<br />

Large<br />

2002<br />

2002<br />

2003<br />

2003<br />

2004<br />

2004<br />

2005<br />

2005<br />

2006<br />

2006<br />

2007<br />

2007<br />

2008<br />

2008<br />

52


(C) <strong>Fund</strong> style<br />

LargeBalance<br />

LargeGrowth<br />

LargeValue<br />

MidBalance<br />

MidGrowith<br />

MidValue<br />

SmallBalance<br />

SmallGrowth<br />

SmallValue<br />

0<br />

10<br />

20<br />

30<br />

40<br />

50<br />

60<br />

70<br />

80<br />

90<br />

100<br />

1983<br />

1984<br />

1985<br />

1986<br />

1987<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

2003<br />

2004<br />

2005<br />

2006<br />

2007<br />

2008<br />

%<br />

53


Figure III. Flow-performance relationship by kernel regression<br />

Estimates of the ‡ow-performance relationships us<strong>in</strong>g kernel regressions <strong>and</strong> their 90% con…dence <strong>in</strong>tervals.<br />

The y-axes represent expected annual net ‡ows <strong>in</strong>to <strong>and</strong> out of non<strong>in</strong>dex funds from 1983 to 1999<br />

(before 2000) <strong>and</strong> from 2000 to 2008 (after 2000). Performance is annual returns m<strong>in</strong>us benchmark returns.<br />

The benchmark returns are the CRSP value weighted <strong>in</strong>dex (CRSP), the S&P500 <strong>in</strong>dex (SP500), returns on<br />

the benchmark <strong>in</strong>dexes designated by the funds (benchmark), <strong>and</strong> the average returns of the funds <strong>in</strong> the<br />

same style category as de…ned by the Morn<strong>in</strong>gstar (style). Style returns <strong>in</strong>clude returns on <strong>in</strong>dex funds but<br />

exclude sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds. The expected annual net ‡ows are estimated after controll<strong>in</strong>g<br />

contemporaneous performance, the second lag of performance, log age, log size, expense ratio, volatility,<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry ‡ow, style ‡ow <strong>and</strong> lagged ‡ow. Log age is the natural logarithm (log) of the months s<strong>in</strong>ce the<br />

<strong>in</strong>ception date of a fund (age). Log size is the log of TNA of a fund divided by the average TNA of sample<br />

funds (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex funds but exclud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds). Expense ratio does not<br />

<strong>in</strong>clude load fees. Volatility is the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of monthly returns over the last two years. Industry<br />

‡ow represents net ‡ows to all equity mutual funds <strong>in</strong> the CRSP database (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational<br />

funds). Style ‡ow is net ‡ows to the funds <strong>in</strong> each of 9 styles (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex funds but exclud<strong>in</strong>g<br />

sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds). <strong>Fund</strong>s are aggregated across share classes, exclud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutional<br />

share classes. The total number of funds is 2,264 over 1983 to 2008 <strong>and</strong> the numbers of observations are<br />

6,771 <strong>and</strong> 10,908 before 2000 <strong>and</strong> after 2000 respectively.<br />

annual flows<br />

annual flows<br />

0.4<br />

0.2<br />

0<br />

­0.2<br />

0.4<br />

0.2<br />

0<br />

­0.2<br />

before 2000<br />

after 2000<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

lagged return over CRSP<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

lagged return over benchmark<br />

annual flows<br />

annual flows<br />

0.4<br />

0.2<br />

0<br />

­0.2<br />

0.4<br />

0.2<br />

0<br />

­0.2<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

lagged return over SP500<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

lagged return over style<br />

54


Figure IV. Flow-performance relationship <strong>and</strong> its sensitivity by OLS regressions<br />

(A) Flow-performance relationship <strong>and</strong> (B) its sensitivity from 1983 to 1999 (before 2000) <strong>and</strong> from<br />

2000 to 2008 (after 2000) for each performance measure. The sensitivity is the …rst derivative of the ‡owperformance<br />

relationship with respect to lagged performance, i.e., 1+2 2 performance <strong>in</strong> Equation (27).<br />

The estimates used for the plots are presented <strong>in</strong> Table III. The relationship is estimated after regress<strong>in</strong>g<br />

annual net fund ‡ows on lagged performance, its square, contemporaneous performance, the second lag of<br />

performance, log age, log size, expense ratio, volatility, <strong>in</strong>dustry ‡ow, <strong>and</strong> style ‡ow. Performance is annual<br />

returns m<strong>in</strong>us benchmark returns. The benchmark returns are the CRSP value weighted <strong>in</strong>dex (CRSP),<br />

the S&P500 <strong>in</strong>dex (SP500), returns on the benchmark <strong>in</strong>dexes designated by the funds (benchmark), <strong>and</strong><br />

the average returns of the funds <strong>in</strong> the same style category as de…ned by the Morn<strong>in</strong>gstar (style). Style<br />

returns <strong>in</strong>clude returns on <strong>in</strong>dex funds but exclude sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds. Log age is the<br />

natural logarithm (log) of the months s<strong>in</strong>ce the <strong>in</strong>ception dates of funds (age). Log size is the log of TNA<br />

of a fund divided by the average TNA of sample funds (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex funds but exclud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds). Expense ratio does not <strong>in</strong>clude load fees. Volatility is the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of<br />

monthly returns over the last two years. Industry ‡ow represents net ‡ows to all equity mutual funds <strong>in</strong> the<br />

CRSP database (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds). Style ‡ow is net ‡ows to the funds <strong>in</strong> each<br />

of 9 styles (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex funds but exclud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds). <strong>Fund</strong>s are aggregated<br />

across share classes, exclud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutional share classes. The total number of funds is 2,264 over 1983 to<br />

2008 <strong>and</strong> the numbers of observations are 6,771 <strong>and</strong> 10,908 before 2000 <strong>and</strong> after 2000 respectively.<br />

annual flows<br />

annual flows<br />

0.5<br />

0<br />

(A) Flow-performance relationship us<strong>in</strong>g OLS regression<br />

before 2000<br />

after 2000<br />

­0.5<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

lagged return over CRSP<br />

0.5<br />

0<br />

­0.5<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

lagged return over benchmark<br />

annual flows<br />

annual flows<br />

0.5<br />

0<br />

­0.5<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

lagged return over SP500<br />

0.5<br />

0<br />

­0.5<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

lagged return over style<br />

55


(Figure IV cont<strong>in</strong>ued)<br />

(B) Sensitivity of the ‡ow-performance relationship us<strong>in</strong>g OLS regression<br />

sensitivity<br />

sensitivity<br />

3<br />

2<br />

1<br />

before 2000<br />

after 2000<br />

0<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

3<br />

2<br />

1<br />

lagged return over CRSP<br />

0<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

lagged return over benchmark<br />

sensitivity<br />

sensitivity<br />

3<br />

2<br />

1<br />

0<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

3<br />

2<br />

1<br />

lagged return over SP500<br />

0<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

lagged return over style<br />

56


Figure V. Market volatility, performance dispersion, <strong>and</strong> performance distribution<br />

(A) The blue l<strong>in</strong>e represents the estimates on square of lagged excess returns relative to the CRSP VW<br />

<strong>in</strong>dex after runn<strong>in</strong>g cross-sectional regressions of annual net ‡ows on the lagged excess return, its square,<br />

<strong>and</strong> other control variables <strong>in</strong> each year. The control variables are described <strong>in</strong> Figure 2. The dash l<strong>in</strong>es are<br />

their 90% con…dence <strong>in</strong>tervals. The sample is U.S. mutual funds whose objectives are outperform<strong>in</strong>g market<br />

<strong>in</strong>dexes as stated <strong>in</strong> their prospectuses <strong>and</strong> which meet sampl<strong>in</strong>g criteria described <strong>in</strong> the paper. The red<br />

dash l<strong>in</strong>e is lagged market volatility as measured by annualized st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of daily return on the<br />

CRSP VW <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>in</strong> the prior year. (B) Performance dispersion is the residual obta<strong>in</strong>ed from the regressions<br />

of the cross-sectional st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of performance on the mean <strong>and</strong> the volatility of the daily CRSP<br />

VW returns. Performance is excess returns over the CRSP VW <strong>in</strong>dex. Market volatility <strong>in</strong>dicator is -1, 0,<br />

<strong>and</strong> +1 if market volatility is low, medium <strong>and</strong> high respectively based on its rank<strong>in</strong>g. (C) The histogram<br />

represents the distribution of excess returns relative to the CRSP VW <strong>in</strong>dex when the volatility of returns on<br />

the CRSP VW <strong>in</strong>dex is low (under 10%) dur<strong>in</strong>g the period from 1982 to 2007. (D) The histogram represents<br />

the distribution of excess returns relative to the CRSP VW <strong>in</strong>dex when the volatility of returns on the CRSP<br />

VW <strong>in</strong>dex is high (over 16%) dur<strong>in</strong>g the period from 1982 to 2007. The volatility is annualized st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

deviation of daily returns <strong>and</strong> ranked <strong>in</strong>to three groups (low/mid/high) over 1982 to 2007.<br />

57


(Figure V cont<strong>in</strong>ued)<br />

59


Figure VI. Flow-performance sensitivity conditional on market volatility<br />

Market volatility is ranked <strong>in</strong>to low, medium <strong>and</strong> high groups based on the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of daily<br />

return on the CRSP VW <strong>in</strong>dex. The sensitivity is the …rst derivative of the relationship with respect to<br />

lagged performance (i.e., Equation (27) <strong>in</strong> the paper). The estimates used for the plots are presented <strong>in</strong> Table<br />

4 (regression (4)). The relationship is estimated after regress<strong>in</strong>g annual net ‡ows <strong>in</strong>to <strong>and</strong> out of non<strong>in</strong>dex<br />

funds on lagged performance, its square, contemporaneous performance, the second lag of performance, log<br />

age, log size, expense ratio, volatility, <strong>in</strong>dustry ‡ow, <strong>and</strong> style ‡ow. Performance is annual returns m<strong>in</strong>us<br />

benchmark returns. The benchmark returns are the CRSP value weighted <strong>in</strong>dex (CRSP), the S&P500 <strong>in</strong>dex<br />

(SP500), returns on the benchmark <strong>in</strong>dexes designated by the funds (benchmark), <strong>and</strong> the average returns of<br />

the funds <strong>in</strong> the same style category as de…ned by the Morn<strong>in</strong>gstar (style). Style returns <strong>in</strong>clude returns on<br />

<strong>in</strong>dex funds but exclude sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds. Log age is the natural logarithm (log) of the<br />

months s<strong>in</strong>ce the <strong>in</strong>ception dates of funds (age). Log size is the log of TNA of a fund divided by the average<br />

TNA of sample funds (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex funds but exclud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds). Expense<br />

ratio does not <strong>in</strong>clude load fees. Volatility is the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of monthly returns over the last two<br />

years. Industry ‡ow represents net ‡ows to all equity mutual funds <strong>in</strong> the CRSP database (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g sector<br />

funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds). Style ‡ow is net ‡ows to the funds <strong>in</strong> each of 9 styles (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex funds<br />

but exclud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds). <strong>Fund</strong>s are aggregated across share classes, exclud<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>stitutional shares. The total number of funds is 2,264 over 1983 to 2008.<br />

sensitivity sensitivity<br />

sensitivity<br />

3<br />

2<br />

1<br />

0<br />

3<br />

2<br />

1<br />

0<br />

low­volatility<br />

high­volatility<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

lagged return over CRSP<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

lagged return over benchmark<br />

sensitivity<br />

sensitivity<br />

3<br />

2<br />

1<br />

0<br />

3<br />

2<br />

1<br />

0<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

lagged return over SP500<br />

­0.2 ­0.1 0 0.1 0.2<br />

lagged return over style<br />

60


Figure VII. Flow-performance relationship us<strong>in</strong>g piecewise OLS regression<br />

The y-axes represent expected annual net ‡ows <strong>in</strong>to <strong>and</strong> out of non<strong>in</strong>dex funds. Performance is annual<br />

excess returns over the CRSP value weighted <strong>in</strong>dex (CRSP VW). See Table VIII for the estimates used to<br />

plot the expected annual net ‡ows. (A) Flow-performance relationship from 1983 to 1999 (before 2000) <strong>and</strong><br />

from 2000 to 2008 (after 2000) (B) The ‡ow-performance relationship <strong>in</strong> the low volatility market <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> the<br />

high volatility market.<br />

(A) Flow-performance relationship before <strong>and</strong> after 2000<br />

annual flows<br />

0.3<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

0<br />

­0.1<br />

­0.2<br />

before 2000<br />

after 2000<br />

­0.25 ­0.2 ­0.15 ­0.1 ­0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25<br />

lagged return over CRSP<br />

(B) Flow-performance relationship conditional on market volatility<br />

annual flows<br />

0.5<br />

0.4<br />

0.3<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

0<br />

­0.1<br />

­0.2<br />

low volatility<br />

high volatility<br />

­0.25 ­0.2 ­0.15 ­0.1 ­0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25<br />

lagged return over CRSP<br />

61


Figure VIII. Flow-performance (rank<strong>in</strong>g) relationship by kernel regression<br />

Estimates of the ‡ow-performance relationships us<strong>in</strong>g kernel regressions suggested by Rob<strong>in</strong>son (1988)<br />

<strong>and</strong> their 90% con…dence <strong>in</strong>tervals. The y-axes represent expected annual net ‡ows <strong>in</strong>to <strong>and</strong> out of non<strong>in</strong>dex<br />

funds from 1983 to 1999 (before 2000) <strong>and</strong> from 2000 to 2008 (after 2000). Performance is rank <strong>in</strong> the<br />

ascend<strong>in</strong>g order based on annual returns m<strong>in</strong>us the CRSP value weighted <strong>in</strong>dex (CRSP), divided by the<br />

total number of funds <strong>in</strong> a given year. The expected annual net ‡ows are estimated after controll<strong>in</strong>g contemporaneous<br />

performance, the second lag of performance, log age, log size, expense ratio, volatility, <strong>in</strong>dustry<br />

‡ow, style ‡ow <strong>and</strong> lagged ‡ow. See Figure 7 for variable descriptions. <strong>Fund</strong>s are aggregated across share<br />

classes, exclud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutional share classes. The total number of funds is 2,264 over 1983 to 2008 <strong>and</strong> the<br />

numbers of observations are 6,771 <strong>and</strong> 10,908 before 2000 <strong>and</strong> after 2000 respectively.<br />

expected annual net flows<br />

0.6<br />

0.5<br />

0.4<br />

0.3<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

0<br />

­0.1<br />

before 2000<br />

after 2000<br />

­0.2<br />

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1<br />

lagged performance rank<br />

62


Figure IX. Flow-performance relationship for <strong>in</strong>dex funds by kernel regression<br />

Estimates of ‡ow-performance relationships for <strong>in</strong>dex funds us<strong>in</strong>g kernel regressions suggested by Rob<strong>in</strong>son<br />

(1988) <strong>and</strong> 90% con…dence <strong>in</strong>tervals (dotted l<strong>in</strong>es). The y-axes represent expected annual net ‡ows <strong>in</strong>to<br />

<strong>and</strong> out of <strong>in</strong>dex funds from 2000 to 2008. Performance is annual returns m<strong>in</strong>us benchmark returns. The<br />

benchmark returns are the CRSP value weighted <strong>in</strong>dex (CRSP), the S&P500 <strong>in</strong>dex (SP500), returns on<br />

the benchmark <strong>in</strong>dexes designated by the funds (benchmark), <strong>and</strong> the average returns of the funds <strong>in</strong> the<br />

same style category as de…ned by the Morn<strong>in</strong>gstar (style). Style returns <strong>in</strong>clude returns on <strong>in</strong>dex funds but<br />

exclude sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds. The expected annual net ‡ows are estimated after controll<strong>in</strong>g<br />

contemporaneous performance, the second lag of performance, log age, log size, expense ratio, volatility,<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry ‡ow, style ‡ow <strong>and</strong> lagged ‡ow. Log age is the natural logarithm (log) of the months s<strong>in</strong>ce the<br />

<strong>in</strong>ception dates of funds (age). Log size is the log of TNA of a fund divided by the average TNA of sample<br />

funds (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex funds but exclud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds). Expense ratio does not<br />

<strong>in</strong>clude load fees. Volatility is the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of monthly returns over the last two years. Industry<br />

‡ow represents net ‡ows to all equity mutual funds <strong>in</strong> the CRSP database (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational<br />

funds). Style ‡ow is net ‡ows to the funds <strong>in</strong> each of 9 styles (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex funds but exclud<strong>in</strong>g<br />

sector funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational funds). <strong>Fund</strong>s are aggregated across share classes, exclud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutional<br />

share classes. The total number of funds is 181 <strong>and</strong> the numbers of observations is 921.<br />

annual flows<br />

annual flows<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

0<br />

­0.1<br />

­0.2<br />

­0.1 ­0.05 0 0.05 0.1<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

0<br />

­0.1<br />

lagged return over CRSP<br />

­0.2<br />

­0.1 ­0.05 0 0.05 0.1<br />

lagged return over benchmark<br />

annual flows<br />

annual flows<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

0<br />

­0.1<br />

­0.2<br />

­0.1 ­0.05 0 0.05 0.1<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

0<br />

­0.1<br />

lagged return over SP500<br />

­0.2<br />

­0.1 ­0.05 0 0.05 0.1<br />

lagged return over style<br />

63

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!