26.07.2013 Views

The Single Income Tax - The 2020 Tax Commission

The Single Income Tax - The 2020 Tax Commission

The Single Income Tax - The 2020 Tax Commission

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

But that argument that a higher CGT would be fairer ignores that it is effectively<br />

a double tax (Section 5.2.2.1) and is also hard to sustain if the tax reduces revenue.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Republican Study Committee reports similar findings to the Adam Smith<br />

Institute:446<br />

In 1977, the top capital gains tax rate was 35 per cent. After five changes<br />

between 1978 and 2003, four that lowered the capital gains rate, the top<br />

capital gains tax rate is currently 15 per cent. This 57 per cent reduction in<br />

the top capital gains tax rate over the last thirty years has coincided with<br />

a fifteen-fold increase in capital gains revenue. From 1977 to 2007, capital<br />

gains revenue increased from $8 billion to $127 billion.<br />

In 1987, Lindsey looked at a proposed increase in the rate of CGT in the United<br />

States. He found that the change could lead to a long term and substantial reduction<br />

in CGT revenue, and that as a result the measure would be regressive.447<br />

<strong>The</strong> obvious objection to these findings is that, while a rise in CGT rates reduces<br />

CGT revenue, it increases <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Tax</strong> revenue. Investors will put less effort into<br />

shifting income into capital gains in order to avoid tax. However more comprehensive<br />

research suggests that, even with a broader set of potential behavioural changes<br />

accounted for, a cut in CGT may still increase revenue.<br />

Table 4.7: Fiscal effects of changes in the Capital Gains <strong>Tax</strong> rate, Entin<br />

Federal budget<br />

Changes to revenue and budget<br />

effects of changes in the capital gains<br />

tax rate ($bn)<br />

20% 24% 28%<br />

Static capital gain tax increase 30.7 54.7 77.5<br />

Loss in personal income tax from weaker economy -28.3 -51.8 -73.5<br />

Net change in personal income tax 2.5 2.9 4.0<br />

Loss in other taxes from weaker economy -15.3 -27.7 -39.0<br />

Dynamic change in total federal revenue (before portfolio<br />

adjustments)<br />

-12.8 -24.8 -35.0<br />

Change in federal outlays due to lower wages -7.4 -13.4 -18.8<br />

Change in federal budget surplus (- indicates smaller<br />

surplus or larger deficit)<br />

Portfolio adjustment<br />

Further reduction in capital gains tax revenue from<br />

reduction in capital stock<br />

-5.4 -11.4 -16.2<br />

-12.0 -21.4 -29.8<br />

Dynamic revenue change with portfolio adjustment -24.9 -46.2 -64.8<br />

Change in federal surplus with portfolio adjustment -17.4 -32.8 -46.0<br />

Entin modelled the effects of raising CGT to 20 per cent, 24 per cent and 28<br />

per cent. <strong>The</strong> first row of Table 4.7 shows that with static increases to the CGT rate,<br />

assuming no change in capital formation and employment, revenues can indeed<br />

446. Ibid<br />

447. Lindsey, L, Capital Gains <strong>Tax</strong>es under the <strong>Tax</strong> Reform Act of 1986: Revenue estimates under various<br />

assumptions, NBER Working Paper No. w2215, 1987<br />

<strong>Tax</strong>Payers’ Alliance | Institute of Directors 229

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!