25.08.2013 Views

Who earns minimum wages in Europe - European Trade Union ...

Who earns minimum wages in Europe - European Trade Union ...

Who earns minimum wages in Europe - European Trade Union ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

.....................................................................................................................................<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong>?<br />

New evidence based on household surveys<br />

—<br />

François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

.....................................................................................................................................<br />

Report 124


<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong>?<br />

New evidence based on household surveys<br />

—<br />

François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

Report 124<br />

european trade union <strong>in</strong>stitute


Brussels, 2012<br />

© Publisher: ETUI aisbl, Brussels<br />

All rights reserved<br />

Pr<strong>in</strong>t: ETUI Pr<strong>in</strong>tshop, Brussels<br />

D/2012/10.574/25<br />

ISBN: 978-2-87452-271-0 (pr<strong>in</strong>t version)<br />

ISBN: 978-2-87452-273-4 (electronic version)<br />

The ETUI is f<strong>in</strong>ancially supported by the <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>Union</strong>. The <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>Union</strong> is not<br />

responsible for any use made of the <strong>in</strong>formation conta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> this publication.


Contents<br />

Executive summary ................................................................................................................................... 5<br />

1. Introduction: M<strong>in</strong>imum <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ................................................................................ 13<br />

2. The study of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>: state of the art ..................................................................... 16<br />

2.1 General issues addressed by the economic literature ............................................... 16<br />

2.2 Central concepts for the analysis of the “bite” of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> ..................... 17<br />

2.3 Exist<strong>in</strong>g comparative studies and available databases ............................................. 21<br />

2.4 Typology of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems ............................................................................... 23<br />

3. M<strong>in</strong>imum <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong>: empirical results ........................................................................ 26<br />

3.1 The qualitative dimension: the <strong>Europe</strong>an diversity<br />

of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems .................................................................................................. 26<br />

3.2 The quantitative dimension: employment <strong>in</strong>cidence, Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices<br />

and characteristics of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners (and their households) .............. 27<br />

3.3 Regression analysis ................................................................................................................ 43<br />

4. Summary and suggestions for further research ................................................................... 48<br />

Statistical appendix ................................................................................................................................ 51<br />

Bibliography .............................................................................................................................................. 63<br />

Report 124<br />

3


Executive summary<br />

Context and objectives<br />

After a period of neglect dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1980s and 1990s, <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> have<br />

re-appeared on political agendas <strong>in</strong> several <strong>Europe</strong>an countries. Although<br />

their critics regularly warn aga<strong>in</strong>st potentially negative effects, notably as<br />

regards low-wage employment, wage floors are widely regarded as useful<br />

<strong>in</strong>struments to protect low-wage workers and to combat ris<strong>in</strong>g levels of<br />

<strong>in</strong>equality and poverty.<br />

Today, the <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>Union</strong> stands out as a traditional stronghold of this type<br />

of labour market policy. With<strong>in</strong> the <strong>Union</strong>, however, there is much diversity<br />

as to the national systems govern<strong>in</strong>g the fix<strong>in</strong>g, implementation, and<br />

monitor<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>. What is more, the persist<strong>in</strong>g differences<br />

among <strong>Europe</strong>an countries with respect to the overall level and distribution<br />

of <strong>wages</strong> create <strong>in</strong>ternational variations <strong>in</strong> the level and bite of exist<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>. The current context of widen<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>equality and a<br />

tight low-wage labour market <strong>in</strong> several Member States might not only<br />

accentuate these differences, but is also likely to generate further <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> as a policy to counter these tendencies.<br />

This study sets out to provide a comprehensive, evidence-based, and up-todate<br />

assessment of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> a range of <strong>Europe</strong>an countries. A first<br />

step towards a better understand<strong>in</strong>g of where <strong>Europe</strong> stands today on this<br />

issue requires to grasp the diversity of <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems, a<br />

key objective of the study at hand. The second objective is to document<br />

<strong>in</strong>ternational differences <strong>in</strong> the so-called "bite" of the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage. This<br />

leads to questions such as "how do national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> compare to the<br />

overall wage distribution?" and "how many people earn <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong><br />

each country?" that are assessed for a set of n<strong>in</strong>e countries from Western,<br />

Central and Eastern <strong>Europe</strong>: Belgium, Bulgaria, Germany, Hungary, Ireland,<br />

Poland, Romania, Spa<strong>in</strong>, and the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom. This sample was designed<br />

to <strong>in</strong>clude countries for which recent evidence has been miss<strong>in</strong>g prior to this<br />

report; <strong>in</strong>deed, recent <strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> Central and Eastern<br />

<strong>Europe</strong>an countries is urgently needed to compare the labour market<br />

outcomes <strong>in</strong> different geographical areas of the <strong>Union</strong>. The report also<br />

<strong>in</strong>cludes Belgium and Germany as examples of countries with complex<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems that are unfortunately not treated <strong>in</strong> many<br />

comparative studies. What is more, the study also overcomes the narrow<br />

focus of extant overviews that have typically focussed only on full-time<br />

employment.<br />

Report 124<br />

5


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

Crucially, the study improves on exist<strong>in</strong>g work by look<strong>in</strong>g beyond aggregate<br />

numbers; it provides a detailed panorama of the population of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage earners <strong>in</strong> each country under <strong>in</strong>vestigation, notably by describ<strong>in</strong>g their<br />

composition <strong>in</strong> terms of a range of socio-demographic characteristics.<br />

Grasp<strong>in</strong>g the diversity of <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

systems<br />

<strong>Europe</strong>an countries are not homogeneous with respect to their <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage policies. Indeed, <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems typically reflect the wider<br />

<strong>in</strong>stitutional context of national labour markets as well as their historical<br />

development. The formerly socialist economies of Central and Eastern<br />

<strong>Europe</strong>an countries are a case <strong>in</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the transition from planned to<br />

market economies, these countries typically developed <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

policies without the back<strong>in</strong>g of strong collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions. As a<br />

result, many of them today operate systems <strong>in</strong> which a s<strong>in</strong>gle wage floor is<br />

fixed at the national level - contrary to countries with strong traditions of<br />

sectoral barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g like Italy or Sweden where trade unions negotiate<br />

different m<strong>in</strong>ima for each sector.<br />

In order to grasp the diversity of <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems, the study<br />

uses a straightforward typology that has both <strong>in</strong>tuitive appeal and fits the<br />

empirical results. It dist<strong>in</strong>guishes between two types of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

systems:<br />

— Type I: the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage that applies to most workers and employees<br />

is determ<strong>in</strong>ed through the decision of a governmental agency or<br />

collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g at the national level. In its ideal-typical form, such<br />

a system leads to a clean cut <strong>in</strong> the wage distribution at the level of the<br />

national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage.<br />

— Type II: the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage that applies to most workers and employees<br />

is determ<strong>in</strong>ed at the <strong>in</strong>fra-national level, for <strong>in</strong>stance <strong>in</strong> sector or regional<br />

negotiations. The ideal-type of this system <strong>in</strong>cludes many different<br />

m<strong>in</strong>ima so that no clear truncation is visible at any particular po<strong>in</strong>t of the<br />

wage distribution. This type of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage system is referred to as a<br />

"complex system".<br />

This typology reveals a geographical stratification of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems.<br />

All of the Nordic countries operate <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage system that are "complex",<br />

i.e. many different m<strong>in</strong>ima co-exist side by side. By contrast, the new<br />

Members States from Central and Eastern <strong>Europe</strong> have "clean-cut" systems,<br />

i.e. the wage distribution is truncated by a <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage that applies to<br />

most workers. The Anglo-Saxon countries <strong>in</strong> the sample (United K<strong>in</strong>gdom<br />

and Ireland) also established systems that apply if not a s<strong>in</strong>gle, but<br />

nevertheless a small number of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> at the national level.<br />

Western Cont<strong>in</strong>ental and Southern <strong>Europe</strong> cannot be classified <strong>in</strong>to one of the<br />

6 Report 124


<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

two types: while Austria, Belgium, Germany, Greece, and Italy have complex<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Cyprus, Spa<strong>in</strong>, and<br />

Portugal resemble more the clean-cut type.<br />

Level of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> and <strong>in</strong>cidence of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage earners<br />

There are two ways to assess the "bite" of a given <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage: (a)<br />

compar<strong>in</strong>g its absolute level across countries and its relative to the national<br />

median wage and (b) look<strong>in</strong>g at the proportion of the labour force that <strong>earns</strong><br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>. The computation of both statistics is tedious due to the coexistence<br />

of many different <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> with<strong>in</strong> most countries. While the<br />

range of different m<strong>in</strong>ima is relatively narrow <strong>in</strong> some countries (<strong>in</strong> 2007, the<br />

lowest m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong> Bulgaria was 0.48 and the highest 0.53 euros per hour),<br />

other countries apply rather unequal rates to different segments of the labour<br />

market (<strong>in</strong> the UK, the lowest <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>in</strong> 2007 was 4.85 and the highest<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> 7.86 euros).<br />

The study deals with this difficulty by comput<strong>in</strong>g employment-weighted<br />

averages of the different national m<strong>in</strong>ima, both absolute and relative to the<br />

national median wage. The latter is a common measure typically referred to<br />

as the Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex. Spa<strong>in</strong> has a very low Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex of 39.3, which means that<br />

the employment-weighted average of the different <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> Spa<strong>in</strong><br />

amounts to around 40 per cent of the Spanish median wage. Bulgaria (41.0),<br />

Romania (44.4), and Poland (47.5) also have relatively low Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices,<br />

contrary to Ireland (52.6) or Hungary (57.0).<br />

Countries with high Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices tend to have a bigger share of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage earners: the higher a <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage is relative to the middle of the<br />

wage distribution, the more people fall with<strong>in</strong> its range. This relationship<br />

comes out <strong>in</strong> the study: as much as 11.5 per cent of Hungarians earn <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong>, but only 3.8 per cent of Spaniards.<br />

In countries like Belgium, Germany, Italy, or Sweden, the national level is not<br />

the most relevant focus of analysis s<strong>in</strong>ce sectoral <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong><br />

predom<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>in</strong> these countries. However, the complexity of sectoral<br />

barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g is such that hardly any statistical <strong>in</strong>formation on Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices or<br />

the number of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> earners is available for complex <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

systems. The study provides novel evidence <strong>in</strong> this regard and estimated the<br />

average of sectoral m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong> Belgium at 59.6 per cent of the Belgium median<br />

wage. The Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex for Germany is estimated at 57.8 per cent. This suggests<br />

that <strong>in</strong> countries with complex systems, the observed wage floors are<br />

relatively high compared to countries with clean-cut systems. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly,<br />

more people tend to earn (sectoral) <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> these countries. In<br />

Belgium, for <strong>in</strong>stance, the study estimates that 11.4 per cent of the labour<br />

force receives sectoral m<strong>in</strong>ima.<br />

Report 124<br />

7


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

Characteristics of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners and their<br />

households<br />

<strong>Trade</strong> unions and policy makers <strong>in</strong> favour of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> typically argue<br />

that the livelihoods of people with low <strong>in</strong>comes are improved after<br />

<strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g wage floors or <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g exist<strong>in</strong>g m<strong>in</strong>ima. Central for this k<strong>in</strong>d of<br />

argumentation is know<strong>in</strong>g who the people are that are found <strong>in</strong> the lower<br />

portion of the <strong>in</strong>come distribution. However, experts on <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong><br />

know surpris<strong>in</strong>gly little about the composition of the group of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

earners. On this po<strong>in</strong>t, the study provides new <strong>in</strong>sights by compar<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> earners to the rest of the labour force with respect to a range of<br />

socio-demographic and job characteristics.<br />

As for the <strong>in</strong>dividual characteristics of workers and employees, the study<br />

notably looks at age, sex, and educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment. Although there is some<br />

diversity among the countries covered <strong>in</strong> the sample, <strong>in</strong> all of them the<br />

population of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners is similar <strong>in</strong> that it is characterised by:<br />

— a lower average age;<br />

— on average more female employment;<br />

— lower levels of educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment than workers with higher <strong>wages</strong>.<br />

Regard<strong>in</strong>g job characteristics, the study compares the two sub-populations<br />

with respect to the share of temporary work contracts and the <strong>in</strong>cidence of<br />

part-time jobs. The latter has been def<strong>in</strong>ed as employments whose average<br />

weekly work hours do not exceed 35 hours. Aga<strong>in</strong>, the data reveals a clear<br />

difference between the two sub-populations <strong>in</strong> all countries. In particular, the<br />

group of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> earners stands out as conta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g:<br />

— a considerably higher share of employees with temporary work contracts;<br />

— a higher share of part time employment than the sub-population with<br />

higher <strong>wages</strong>.<br />

What are the overall liv<strong>in</strong>g conditions of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners? To shed light<br />

on this question, the report exploits harmonized survey <strong>in</strong>formation on<br />

household characteristics like the average household size, the total disposable<br />

household <strong>in</strong>come, and the risk of poverty. All countries <strong>in</strong> the sample show a<br />

similar pattern <strong>in</strong> terms of household size: the population of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

earners consistently live <strong>in</strong> households that are on average larger compared to<br />

the population with higher <strong>wages</strong>. Unsurpris<strong>in</strong>gly, the average disposable<br />

household <strong>in</strong>come is also consistently lower <strong>in</strong> households with <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage earners. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>in</strong> most of the countries <strong>in</strong> the sample, the risk of<br />

poverty of the household is on average considerably higher for the population<br />

of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners.<br />

8 Report 124


Ma<strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum <strong>wages</strong> cont<strong>in</strong>ue to stir controversial policy debates. The current<br />

economic climate <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> might contribute to <strong>in</strong>crease the pressure on<br />

<strong>wages</strong> at the bottom of the wage distribution and, as a consequence, renew the<br />

<strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> wage floors as a tool to protect workers and employees. This study<br />

contributes to a better understand<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> by provid<strong>in</strong>g a solid<br />

empirical assessment of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage policies and their socio-economic<br />

consequences for a range of <strong>Europe</strong>an countries.<br />

An obstacle to provid<strong>in</strong>g comparable <strong>in</strong>formation on wage m<strong>in</strong>ima for<br />

different countries is the <strong>in</strong>stitutional diversity of <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

systems. This diversity reflects the historical evolution of each of the national<br />

collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g systems. While one has to acknowledge the existence of<br />

national idiosyncrasies, it is nevertheless useful to dist<strong>in</strong>guish <strong>Europe</strong>an<br />

countries with the help of a straightforward typology. Central and Eastern<br />

<strong>Europe</strong>an countries, the UK and Ireland, as well as Luxembourg, the<br />

Netherlands, Cyprus, Spa<strong>in</strong>, and Portugal operate <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems<br />

that produce a "clean cut" <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>come distribution. By contrast, all of the<br />

Nordic countries, Austria, Belgium, Germany, Greece, and Italy operate<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems that are "complex", i.e. many different m<strong>in</strong>ima coexist<br />

side by side so that the left tail of the wage distribution is much smoother<br />

<strong>in</strong> these countries.<br />

In addition to qualitative differences between <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems, the<br />

report documents <strong>in</strong>ternational variations <strong>in</strong> the (absolute and relative) levels<br />

of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>. While these levels follow no clear geographical pattern, it<br />

appears that complex systems are more likely to generate relatively high wage<br />

floors compared to systems that determ<strong>in</strong>e a s<strong>in</strong>gle wage <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> at the<br />

national level.<br />

An important contribution of the report is to provide a statistical panorama of<br />

the population of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners. Compared to the rest of the<br />

population, the empirical results show that this group is characterised by a<br />

lower average age; on average more female employment; lower levels of<br />

educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment than workers with higher <strong>wages</strong>; a considerably<br />

higher share of employees with temporary work contracts; and a higher share<br />

of part time employment than the sub-population with higher <strong>wages</strong>. Even<br />

more important <strong>in</strong> terms of the affected <strong>in</strong>dividuals' well be<strong>in</strong>g is the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g<br />

that <strong>in</strong> all countries <strong>in</strong> the sample <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners live <strong>in</strong> bigger<br />

households that dispose of significantly lower <strong>in</strong>come and that are at a higher<br />

risk of liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> poverty.<br />

Report 124<br />

9


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

Figures and table: Distributions and m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong><br />

different types of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems<br />

Figure a Example of a clean-cut system<br />

0 2 4 6 8<br />

percent<br />

10 Report 124<br />

Bulgaria (2007)<br />

0 1 2 3 4 5<br />

gross hourly wage (euros)<br />

Figure b Example of a complex system<br />

0 2 4 6 8 10<br />

percent<br />

Belgium (2007)<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50<br />

gross hourly wage (euros)<br />

Source: EU-SILC; current 2007 euros; th<strong>in</strong> vertical l<strong>in</strong>es represent levels of exist<strong>in</strong>g m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> each country.


Table a Level of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>, share of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners, and Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices per country (2007)<br />

Share of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners accord<strong>in</strong>g to different<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (per cent)<br />

Employment-weighted Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex accord<strong>in</strong>g<br />

to different <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (per cent) 2<br />

Level of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (current euros)<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum wage<br />

equal to 50 per cent<br />

of median wage<br />

Sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

Interprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

Sector <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

Interprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

Employmentweighted<br />

average<br />

of m<strong>in</strong>ima2 Highest<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

Lowest<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

Obs.<br />

TYPE I COUNTRIES<br />

12.2<br />

4.7<br />

—<br />

—<br />

5.8<br />

—<br />

—<br />

41.0<br />

57.0<br />

0.53<br />

1.51<br />

0.53<br />

1.51<br />

0.48<br />

1.51<br />

3904<br />

6513<br />

Bulgaria<br />

Hungary<br />

8.8<br />

11.5<br />

9.2<br />

—<br />

—<br />

—<br />

—<br />

52.6<br />

47.5<br />

8.37<br />

1.42<br />

8.48<br />

1.43<br />

5.93<br />

1.14<br />

3361<br />

10.4<br />

8.3<br />

8.9<br />

4.9<br />

10452<br />

5055<br />

—<br />

—<br />

—<br />

—<br />

44.4<br />

39.9<br />

0.69<br />

3.41<br />

0.69<br />

3.46<br />

0.69<br />

2.42<br />

7.9<br />

7.7<br />

—<br />

3.8<br />

9.5<br />

—<br />

53.2<br />

7.78<br />

7.86<br />

4.85<br />

11327<br />

7029<br />

Ireland<br />

Poland<br />

Romania<br />

Spa<strong>in</strong><br />

United K<strong>in</strong>gdom<br />

TYPE II COUNTRIES<br />

6.6<br />

11.4<br />

14.3<br />

19.0 3<br />

6.9<br />

—<br />

59.6<br />

57.8<br />

51.9<br />

—<br />

9.22<br />

7.63<br />

13.21<br />

12.21<br />

7.80<br />

3.91<br />

5100<br />

8833<br />

Belgium<br />

Germany<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

Notes<br />

1 Germany SOEP, EU-SILC for all other countries<br />

2 Weight<strong>in</strong>g variables depend on differentiation of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>; employment weighted by sector (and region for Germany)<br />

3 Figure is not corrected for <strong>in</strong>complete collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g coverage at the sector level; <strong>in</strong> Germany, most sectors do not apply erga omnes rules, i.e. only trade union members are covered by the<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage. The figure <strong>in</strong> the table corresponds to the proportion of the German work force that <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> if an erga omnes rule applied <strong>in</strong> all sectors.<br />

Report 124<br />

11


1. Introduction:<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong><br />

After a phase of “conscious neglect dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1980s and 1990s” (ILO, 2010;<br />

p. 63), <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> 1 have re-appeared on political agendas around the<br />

world. Although their critics regularly warn aga<strong>in</strong>st potentially negative<br />

effects, notably as regards low-wage employment, wage floors are widely<br />

regarded as useful <strong>in</strong>struments to protect low-wage workers and to combat<br />

ris<strong>in</strong>g levels of <strong>in</strong>equality and poverty. Today, <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> exist <strong>in</strong> one<br />

form or another <strong>in</strong> around 90 % of countries <strong>in</strong> the world (ILO, 2010), with<br />

<strong>Europe</strong> stand<strong>in</strong>g out as a traditional stronghold of this type of labour market<br />

policy.<br />

Follow<strong>in</strong>g episodes without mandatory wage floors, the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom and<br />

Ireland adopted statutory national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> 1999 and 2000,<br />

respectively, thereby jo<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the majority of their <strong>Europe</strong>an neighbours:<br />

Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Spa<strong>in</strong>, France, Latvia, Lithuania,<br />

Luxembourg, Hungary, Malta, the Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Romania,<br />

Slovenia, and Slovakia. Two Candidate Countries for Membership <strong>in</strong> the<br />

<strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>Union</strong> also have national statutory <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (Croatia and<br />

Turkey). Belgium and Greece have a national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage too, but it is set<br />

by collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g agreements (<strong>in</strong> Belgium the collective agreement<br />

acquires legal force by royal decree and supplemented by sectoral m<strong>in</strong>ima).<br />

Two Member States of the <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>Union</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> a system of statutory<br />

national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> that does not cover the majority of employees:<br />

Germany and Cyprus. In the former, <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> are set for specific<br />

sectors under the provisions of the Posted Workers Act (Arbeitnehmer<br />

Entsendegesetz). The Cypriot <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> are def<strong>in</strong>ed for a restricted<br />

number of occupational groups (salesmen, clerks, auxiliary health care staff<br />

and auxiliary staff <strong>in</strong> nursery schools, crèches and schools). A somewhat<br />

similar system exists <strong>in</strong> the Former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, a<br />

Candidate Country, where national m<strong>in</strong>ima are collectively negotiated for full<br />

time employees <strong>in</strong> the textile, leather, and shoes <strong>in</strong>dustry. F<strong>in</strong>ally, there are<br />

several <strong>Europe</strong>an countries without national statutory <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>:<br />

Austria, Denmark, Italy, F<strong>in</strong>land, Sweden, Iceland, Norway, and Switzerland.<br />

However, sector-level agreements often have erga omnes applicability <strong>in</strong><br />

these countries and therefore function as a collectively negotiated <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage.<br />

1. This report def<strong>in</strong>es "<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>" as <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g not only statutory wage floors, but also m<strong>in</strong>ima<br />

that are def<strong>in</strong>ed through collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g at national and/or sectoral level. An overview about<br />

the different mechanisms through which <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> are set <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> is provided below<br />

(see Table 2).<br />

Report 124<br />

13


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

Advocates of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> typically use one of the two follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

arguments to defend the <strong>in</strong>troduction or <strong>in</strong>crease of wage floors. They<br />

typically argue that <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (a) affect the wage distribution so as to<br />

reduce overall wage <strong>in</strong>equality and/or (b) directly improve the liv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

conditions of workers <strong>in</strong> the lower tail of the wage distribution.<br />

Unfortunately, scholars of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> know little about some of the<br />

basic statistical facts that underp<strong>in</strong> both types of argumentation.<br />

In order to provide a sound statistical basis for the first argument, one would<br />

arguably want to know more about how the observed diversity of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage systems is l<strong>in</strong>ked to <strong>in</strong>ternational variations <strong>in</strong> the shapes of wage<br />

distributions. On this po<strong>in</strong>t, we document how two types of systems generate<br />

contrast<strong>in</strong>g wage distributions: countries operat<strong>in</strong>g "clean-cut systems" are<br />

associated with wage distributions that are truncated at the level of the<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>; <strong>in</strong> this type of system, the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage affects a very<br />

specific segment of the distribution. By contrast, <strong>in</strong> "complex systems" many<br />

different m<strong>in</strong>ima co-exist so that the left tail of the distribution is more or less<br />

bell-shaped; as a consequence, <strong>in</strong> these countries <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage policies<br />

affect <strong>in</strong>dividuals at different strata of the distribution, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g relatively<br />

well-paid groups.<br />

Also the second argument raises fundamental questions that have not yet<br />

been answered satisfactorily <strong>in</strong> the literature. These questions <strong>in</strong>clude: How<br />

many people earn <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> Northern, Western, Central, or Eastern<br />

<strong>Europe</strong>an countries? Most extant studies on this question are outdated and<br />

exclude several key countries from Central and Eastern <strong>Europe</strong>. Crucially, we<br />

also still know little about the people that are affected by <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

policies. For <strong>in</strong>stance, to what extent do they differ from the rest of the labour<br />

force <strong>in</strong> terms of <strong>in</strong>dividual, job, and household characteristics ?<br />

This report presents comprehensive statistical <strong>in</strong>formation allow<strong>in</strong>g to map<br />

the impact of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong>. While statistics on the general level<br />

of national statutory <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> are published by <strong>in</strong>ternational data<br />

providers on an annual basis, detailed <strong>in</strong>formation on specific groups of<br />

employees has to be computed from <strong>in</strong>dividual-level labour market surveys.<br />

The results of this report are based on large, representative surveys with<br />

micro-data for a set of <strong>Europe</strong>an countries: the <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>Union</strong> Survey on<br />

Income and Liv<strong>in</strong>g Conditions (EU-SILC) and the German Socio-economic<br />

panel (GSOEP).<br />

14 Report 124


Outl<strong>in</strong>e of the report<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

The overall objective of this report is to provide statistical evidence on the<br />

impact of the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage on <strong>Europe</strong>an labour markets. This objective has<br />

been addressed <strong>in</strong> two complementary steps, one of conceptual (Section 2)<br />

and the other of empirical (Section 3) character.<br />

Section 2 presents a review of the literature on <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> and<br />

summarizes the central issues addressed by the extensive research <strong>in</strong> this<br />

area. We also recapitulate the key concepts for the analysis of the “bite” of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> as well as exist<strong>in</strong>g data. In order to grasp the <strong>in</strong>ternational<br />

diversity of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage policies, we <strong>in</strong>troduce a typology of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage systems that contrasts "clean-cut systems" (mostly found <strong>in</strong> the new<br />

Members States and Anglo-Saxon countries) and "complex systems" (such as<br />

Italy, Germany, Belgium, and the Nordic countries).<br />

Turn<strong>in</strong>g to the empirical part of the report, Section 3 presents qualitative and<br />

quantitative data on <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> for a selection of n<strong>in</strong>e countries from<br />

Western, Central and Eastern <strong>Europe</strong>: Belgium, Bulgaria, Germany, Hungary,<br />

Ireland, Poland, Romania, Spa<strong>in</strong>, and the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom. Draw<strong>in</strong>g on the<br />

typology of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems, this section documents the l<strong>in</strong>k between<br />

the <strong>in</strong>ternational diversity <strong>in</strong> the way <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> are set and the shapes<br />

of observed wage distributions (Section 3.1).<br />

Section 3.2 <strong>in</strong>vestigates for each country how many and what k<strong>in</strong>d of people<br />

earn <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> at the national and sector level. We present a series of<br />

empirical results that measure different aspects of the bite of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong>, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g estimates of the Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex; the size and composition of the<br />

employment spike around the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage at the national and sector level;<br />

and the <strong>in</strong>dividual, job, and household characteristics of the population of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners. In particular, we assess for each of the selected<br />

countries the relationship between <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> and age, sex, level of<br />

education, temporary work, work<strong>in</strong>g time, sector of activity, household size,<br />

household <strong>in</strong>come, and poverty risk. We also carried out a scenario analysis<br />

that looks at the employment consequences of a hypothetical policy that<br />

would <strong>in</strong>troduce a <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage fixed at 50 % of the national median wage<br />

<strong>in</strong> all n<strong>in</strong>e countries covered by this study.<br />

In order to assess the relative impact of <strong>in</strong>dividual and job characteristics on<br />

the likelihood of earn<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage, the report also provides results of<br />

a logistic regression for each of the countries <strong>in</strong> the sample (Section 3.3). The<br />

f<strong>in</strong>al section summarizes the conceptual and empirical f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs and suggests<br />

directions for further research on <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong>.<br />

Report 124<br />

15


2. The study of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>:<br />

state of the art<br />

2.1 General issues addressed by the economic<br />

literature<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ce the early 20th century, economists have been engaged <strong>in</strong> vivid academic<br />

controversies on <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>. Over time, this vast body of literature has<br />

grown beyond the possibility of synthesis. In what follows we will highlight<br />

some of the ma<strong>in</strong> issues addressed <strong>in</strong> the academic literature on wage floors.<br />

By far the most controversially and frequently discussed issue are the<br />

employment effects of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>. Although the conventional textbook<br />

labour market model clearly predicts disemployment effects follow<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

<strong>in</strong>troduction of a b<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage (Stigler, 1946; Cahuc and<br />

Zylberberg, 2004), a theoretical case for positive employment effects has also<br />

been formulated (notably by Card and Krueger, 1995). In light of this<br />

theoretical ambiguity, economists have mobilised a variety of methods (timeseries<br />

analysis, cross-section and panel data, controlled experiments rely<strong>in</strong>g<br />

on difference-<strong>in</strong>-differences estimators, identification of substitution and<br />

scale effects, dist<strong>in</strong>ction between effects on employment and hours, etc) <strong>in</strong> an<br />

on-go<strong>in</strong>g attempt to measure the underly<strong>in</strong>g employment elasticities. This<br />

body of research failed to establish a last<strong>in</strong>g consensus, with some researchers<br />

conclud<strong>in</strong>g from extant evidence that employment elasticities are<br />

significantly negative (Brown et al. 1982; Neumark and Wascher, 2004,<br />

2008), while others defend the opposite conclusion (Card and Krueger, 1995).<br />

A reconciliatory position <strong>in</strong> this debate is the view that any employment<br />

effects (be their positive or negative) are probably very small (Kennan, 1995;<br />

Dolado et al., 1996; ILO, 2010).<br />

A second group of issues concerns the impact of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> on the<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong>come distribution, the household <strong>in</strong>come distribution, and<br />

poverty. These issues are of course related to the first one given that one needs<br />

to make assumptions about potential employment consequences <strong>in</strong> order to<br />

anticipate the effects of a <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage on <strong>in</strong>equality or poverty. Typically,<br />

economists have attempted to measure the net result of two effects: the<br />

(positive or negative) employment effect that results from changes <strong>in</strong> labour<br />

demand, and a (positive) wage effect that accrues to <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners<br />

that rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> employment.<br />

The impact of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> on <strong>in</strong>equality and poverty also raises a range<br />

of new questions: To what extent do <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> lead to<br />

hikes <strong>in</strong> other <strong>wages</strong> ? Do <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong>-wage earners live <strong>in</strong> households situated<br />

16 Report 124


<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

at the bottom, middle, or top of the (<strong>in</strong>dividual or household) <strong>in</strong>come<br />

distribution ? And are they ma<strong>in</strong>ly young workers that will “grow out” of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage jobs as they move up career ladders, or are other age groups<br />

for whom <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> could be a more permanent prospect also<br />

affected ?<br />

A range of studies suggest that a substantial share of the benefits of higher<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> accrue <strong>in</strong> households whose <strong>in</strong>comes already lie above<br />

poverty level, and that many <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners are teenagers who will<br />

see their earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g as they acquire experience and seniority (see the<br />

overviews <strong>in</strong> OECD, 1998; Fairchild, 2004). However, other studies have<br />

found “considerable evidence of a poverty-reduc<strong>in</strong>g effect of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong>” for some sub-populations (Addison and Blackburn, 1999; p. 404) or a<br />

negative relationship between the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage and overall <strong>in</strong>equality<br />

(Koeniger, Leonardi and Nunziata, 2007). A serious problem of this literature<br />

is that these questions have been almost exclusively analysed with data from<br />

the United States; especially cross-country comparisons of <strong>in</strong>equality and<br />

poverty effects of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> are rare. This is unfortunate because<br />

national employment systems are likely to <strong>in</strong>fluence the l<strong>in</strong>k between<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> and the overall earn<strong>in</strong>gs distribution. For <strong>in</strong>stance, so-called<br />

“knock-on” or “ripple effects”, i.e. the phenomenon that a <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

hike will <strong>in</strong>duce wage <strong>in</strong>creases higher up <strong>in</strong> the wage distribution, are likely<br />

to depend on the <strong>in</strong>cidence and strength of collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g,<br />

unionisation, and other country-specific <strong>in</strong>stitutions such as the employment<br />

protection legislation (Dolado et al., 1996; Checci and Lucifora, 2002;<br />

Neumark, Schweitzer and Wascher, 2004).<br />

A third set of questions asks to what extent <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong>teract with<br />

other economic variables. This strand of research has attempted to establish<br />

l<strong>in</strong>ks between wage floors and variables such as the general price level,<br />

unemployment, tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g decisions, or economic growth (e.g. Scarpetta, 1996;<br />

Fanti and Gori, 2011). In light of the considerable theoretical and empirical<br />

difficulties to reach robust conclusions on relatively direct consequences of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (such as their effect on low-wage employment), it is not<br />

surpris<strong>in</strong>g that no consistent evidence has yet emerged on more <strong>in</strong>direct<br />

effects.<br />

2.2 Central concepts for the analysis of the “bite” of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong><br />

All issues mentioned above are clearly relevant to understand the impact of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> for the work<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>Europe</strong>an labour markets. The purpose of<br />

this report is to produce a range of more fundamental statistics that are<br />

currently either outdated or unavailable. Although most of these statistics<br />

will be <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g heuristics for their own sake - e.g. by allow<strong>in</strong>g to document<br />

and to compare the bite of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> across <strong>Europe</strong> - it should be<br />

noted that answer<strong>in</strong>g more analytical questions also requires sound evidence<br />

Report 124<br />

17


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

on both the bite of exist<strong>in</strong>g m<strong>in</strong>ima and the socio-demographic composition<br />

of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners. The employment effect of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> is a<br />

case <strong>in</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t: given that different socio-demographic groups typically have<br />

different employment elasticities (Fitzenberger, 2009), a first step <strong>in</strong><br />

estimat<strong>in</strong>g employment consequences is to pa<strong>in</strong>t an accurate picture of the<br />

population of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners. Similarly, the impact of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong> on <strong>in</strong>equality and poverty can only be assessed correctly with detailed<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation on the characteristics of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners.<br />

This report sheds light on the impact of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> by apply<strong>in</strong>g state-ofthe<br />

art concepts to micro-data from a set of <strong>Europe</strong>an countries. The bite of<br />

national wage floors can notably be gauged by estimat<strong>in</strong>g different versions of<br />

the “Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex” and the “employment spike”.<br />

2.2.1 The Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex<br />

Named after its first formulation <strong>in</strong> Kaitz (1970), this <strong>in</strong>dex is a<br />

straightforward method to relate the absolute level of the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage to<br />

other <strong>wages</strong>. Indeed, a direct comparison of absolute levels of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong> is not mean<strong>in</strong>gful if countries differ with respect to the distribution of<br />

productivities: <strong>in</strong> a country with high average productivity, the bite of a<br />

relatively low wage floor might be weak; <strong>in</strong> a low-productivity country,<br />

however, the same <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage could have a much stronger impact.<br />

In its most basic version, the Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex is def<strong>in</strong>ed as the ratio of the<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage to the average wage of the work<strong>in</strong>g population. The Kaitz<br />

<strong>in</strong>dex is thus a measure of the “bite” of the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage: small values<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicate that the wage floor is a long way from the centre of the earn<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

distribution and its impact therefore potentially low; conversely, a high Kaitz<br />

<strong>in</strong>dex reveals that the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage is close to the centre of the distribution<br />

and that it potentially affects a larger number of employees. It should be<br />

noted, however, that the Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex alone does not allow to draw any<br />

conclusion about whether a given level of the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage is economically<br />

desirable or not: this question can only be addressed with additional<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation such as the structure of wage costs and the productivity of<br />

different types of workers. In addition, as Dolado et al. (1996) po<strong>in</strong>t out, the<br />

Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex may misrepresent the impact of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> countries<br />

where other <strong>in</strong>stitutions such as benefit systems act as effective wage floors<br />

(ibid., p. 325).<br />

In certa<strong>in</strong> countries, such as Germany or Italy, the computation of Kaitz<br />

<strong>in</strong>dices is relatively complex due to the existence of numerous m<strong>in</strong>ima<br />

negotiated at sector-level. But even for countries with a s<strong>in</strong>gle national<br />

statutory <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> it is often advisable to calculate separate Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices for<br />

different wage or skill groups <strong>in</strong> order to reflect that the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage bites<br />

deeper for lower paid employees (<strong>in</strong> this case the numerator of the <strong>in</strong>dex is the<br />

same for all employees, but the denom<strong>in</strong>ator decreases if one considers a<br />

group of employees with lower average earn<strong>in</strong>gs). Indeed, the aggregate Kaitz<br />

18 Report 124


<strong>in</strong>dex may be similar across countries but mask compositional differences<br />

(OECD 1998). In this case, compar<strong>in</strong>g the basic <strong>in</strong>dex between dissimilar<br />

countries might lead to serious mis<strong>in</strong>terpretations. In order to improve its<br />

comparability, several adjustments to the basic Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex have been<br />

proposed <strong>in</strong> the literature:<br />

— The composition of the population affected by the Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex might<br />

differ across countries; it is therefore advisable to compare <strong>in</strong>dices for<br />

groups with similar characteristics (such as age, gender, occupation,<br />

educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment, contract type etc.).<br />

— Most <strong>Europe</strong>an countries apply lower sub-m<strong>in</strong>ima for young or<br />

<strong>in</strong>experienced workers (e.g. teenagers), ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong> an attempt to curb<br />

potential disemployment effects for these groups. International<br />

comparability requires the use of different Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices for groups<br />

affected by sub-m<strong>in</strong>ima.<br />

— Although most analysts compute the <strong>in</strong>dex with average earn<strong>in</strong>gs as<br />

denom<strong>in</strong>ator, us<strong>in</strong>g median earn<strong>in</strong>gs might yield more comparable<br />

results. The reason for this is that countries with higher wage dispersion<br />

also have lower <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (OECD 1998). A Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex based on<br />

median earn<strong>in</strong>gs is less affected by the shape of the overall wage<br />

distribution than an <strong>in</strong>dex based on average earn<strong>in</strong>gs.<br />

— International comparisons of Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices are sensitive to the <strong>in</strong>clusion<br />

of bonuses, overtime, and other additional payments; countries <strong>in</strong> which<br />

the <strong>in</strong>cidence of such payments is large will display a non-adjusted Kaitz<br />

<strong>in</strong>dex (i.e. exclud<strong>in</strong>g additional payments) that overestimates the<br />

effective bite of the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage.<br />

— Conversely, the basic Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex can lead to flawed comparisons if gross<br />

earn<strong>in</strong>gs are used <strong>in</strong>stead of net earn<strong>in</strong>gs: the more a country's tax<br />

system is progressive, the more the gross Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex understates the bite<br />

of the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage.<br />

— F<strong>in</strong>ally, it is important to take <strong>in</strong>stitutional differences <strong>in</strong>to account when<br />

compar<strong>in</strong>g Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices. For <strong>in</strong>stance, national labour <strong>in</strong>stitutions differ<br />

<strong>in</strong> the extent to which hikes <strong>in</strong> the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage are transmitted further<br />

up <strong>in</strong> the wage structure. As a consequence, Dolado et al. (1996) argue<br />

that it is safer to analyse changes over time than cross-country<br />

differences, especially <strong>in</strong> situations of considerable <strong>in</strong>stitutional diversity<br />

between countries.<br />

2.2.2 The employment spike<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

The distance between the wage floor and the centre of the earn<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

distribution is a useful heuristic to measure the bite of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>. This<br />

be<strong>in</strong>g said, the Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex alone cannot give a complete picture of the impact<br />

Report 124<br />

19


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>. The case of Sweden illustrates this po<strong>in</strong>t: although the<br />

Swedish Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex is relatively high compared to other <strong>Europe</strong>an countries<br />

(Neumark and Wascher (2004) estimate it at 0.52), nobody actually receives<br />

the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage <strong>in</strong> Sweden. Despite its relatively high level, the Swedish<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage fails to bite due to other features of the earn<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>in</strong> Sweden, especially the strong <strong>in</strong>cidence of collective<br />

barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g. A complementary heuristic for the analysis of the bite of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> is to measure the “spike” of employments that are situated at<br />

or near the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage. The more employees are clustered around the<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong>, the higher is its bite.<br />

To be sure, conventional neoclassical models of the labour market do not<br />

predict any employment spikes. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to such models, the earn<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

distribution will be truncated and workers whose marg<strong>in</strong>al productivity falls<br />

below the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage will be laid off. Empirical research on wage<br />

distributions has documented, however, that this view is seriously flawed: <strong>in</strong><br />

many countries the existence of a <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage has lead to visible<br />

employment spikes at or near the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong>. Possible explanations for this<br />

phenomenon are that employers are able to afford at least part of the higher<br />

wage costs, either by tapp<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to exist<strong>in</strong>g rents (profits) or by pass<strong>in</strong>g these<br />

costs on to consumers. An alternative explanation is that the productivity of<br />

below-<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> employees can be raised through tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g or organisational<br />

changes so as to make their employment profitable at the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage.<br />

Similar to the case of the Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex, cross-country comparability requires<br />

exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the employment spike for similar groups of employees. For<br />

<strong>in</strong>stance, an exclusive focus on the spike <strong>in</strong> the overall wage distribution<br />

might overlook differences <strong>in</strong> employment spikes for categories such as<br />

gender, age, occupation, education, sector, etc.<br />

Depend<strong>in</strong>g on the research question, one might also be <strong>in</strong>terested by the size<br />

and characteristics of the population that is remunerated below certa<strong>in</strong><br />

threshold values, for <strong>in</strong>stance when assess<strong>in</strong>g the impact of a hypothetical rise<br />

<strong>in</strong> the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage (or the Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex) to a higher level. Such a “shadow<br />

spike” can yield <strong>in</strong>formation on the bite of the hypothetical rise <strong>in</strong> the<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage by <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g how many and what types of employees would<br />

be affected <strong>in</strong> such a scenario. It should be noted, however, that the “shadow<br />

spike” can differ substantially from the employment spike that will be<br />

observed if the hypothetical <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage <strong>in</strong>crease is actually implemented.<br />

The difference between the two spikes might stem from several factors: a<br />

higher <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage might attract new employees <strong>in</strong>to the labour force,<br />

thereby chang<strong>in</strong>g its socio-demographic composition; conversely, some<br />

employees <strong>in</strong> the shadow spike might be laid off if the higher <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

renders their employment unprofitable.<br />

20 Report 124


<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

2.3 Exist<strong>in</strong>g comparative studies and available<br />

databases<br />

We identified several extensive databases conta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g statistical and/or<br />

qualitative <strong>in</strong>formation on basic features of <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

systems. First, the OECD M<strong>in</strong>imum Wage Database 2 conta<strong>in</strong>s time series for<br />

some of the ma<strong>in</strong> variables of <strong>in</strong>terest, such as national levels of statutory<br />

m<strong>in</strong>ima (<strong>in</strong> local currencies and PPP-adjusted) and gross Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices (with<br />

both average and median earn<strong>in</strong>gs as denom<strong>in</strong>ator). The OECD provides<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> for different pay periods (hourly, weekly,<br />

monthly, annually) and allows to analyse their evolution over the long run: for<br />

some countries, the time-series data goes back to the 1960s (France, Greece,<br />

Luxembourg, Netherlands, Spa<strong>in</strong>). For <strong>Europe</strong>an countries, the OECD<br />

database conta<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>formation up to the year 2010. A limitation of this source<br />

is that it does not allow to dist<strong>in</strong>guish different groups of employees. All Kaitz<br />

<strong>in</strong>dices are calculated with reference to full-time employees and no separate<br />

<strong>in</strong>dices are provided for younger employees for which sub-m<strong>in</strong>ima may apply<br />

<strong>in</strong> different countries. While the OECD database allows to compare <strong>Europe</strong>an<br />

experiences to non-EU countries with national statutory <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong><br />

(Australia, Canada, Japan, Korea, Mexico, New Zealand, Turkey, and the<br />

United States), it excludes countries <strong>in</strong> which <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> are established<br />

through sector-level collective agreements (such as Germany, Italy, and the<br />

Scand<strong>in</strong>avian countries).<br />

The second source is the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage data published by Eurostat 3 . This<br />

database is very similar to the OECD <strong>in</strong> that it also conta<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>formation on<br />

gross levels of national statutory <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> and gross Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices<br />

(albeit only for monthly rates and only with average earn<strong>in</strong>gs as<br />

denom<strong>in</strong>ator). Moreover, Eurostat also excludes Germany, Italy, Cyprus,<br />

Austria, Switzerland, Iceland, and the Scand<strong>in</strong>avian countries due to the lack<br />

of a national statutory <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage <strong>in</strong> these countries. By contrast,<br />

Eurostat provides data for several Eastern and Central <strong>Europe</strong>an countries<br />

not covered by the OECD (Bulgaria, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Malta,<br />

Romania, Slovenia, and Croatia). The longitud<strong>in</strong>al coverage of the Eurostat<br />

data is somewhat shorter (1999-2009) compared to the OECD series.<br />

The third <strong>in</strong>ternational source, the ILO M<strong>in</strong>imum Wage Database 4 , is quite<br />

different from the two preced<strong>in</strong>g databases. While the ILO data is less useful<br />

to trace the chronological evolution of statutory <strong>wages</strong> floors and their<br />

relation to average or median earn<strong>in</strong>gs, it conta<strong>in</strong>s valuable qualitative<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation on many features of national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> systems such as<br />

the national determ<strong>in</strong>ation mechanism, the coverage of exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong>, adjustment mechanisms, and control and enforcement procedures. In<br />

addition, the ILO provides detailed <strong>in</strong>formation on current levels of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

2. http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=RHMW<br />

3. http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/statistics_expla<strong>in</strong>ed/<strong>in</strong>dex.php/M<strong>in</strong>imum_wage_statistics<br />

4. http://www.ilo.org/travaildatabase/servlet/<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><strong>wages</strong><br />

Report 124<br />

21


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

<strong>wages</strong>, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g exist<strong>in</strong>g sub-m<strong>in</strong>ima. The coverage of the database is much<br />

broader compared to both the OECD and Eurostat: the ILO database <strong>in</strong>cludes<br />

all 100 ILO member countries, i.e. also the countries <strong>in</strong> which <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong> are set through collective agreements at the sub-national level (such as<br />

<strong>in</strong> Austria, Germany, or Italy). A drawback of the ILO data is that its last<br />

update dates back to September 2006.<br />

Next, the Hans-Böckler-Stiftung ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>s an extensive database on<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> 5 via the Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaftliches Institut<br />

(WSI). This database not only monitors the development of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong> Germany tariff sectors, but also provides regular updates on levels of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> for many <strong>Europe</strong>an and non-<strong>Europe</strong>an countries.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, the <strong>Europe</strong>an Industrial Relations Observatory 6 publishes regular<br />

country reports with qualitative <strong>in</strong>formation on labour market <strong>in</strong>stitutions.<br />

These reports typically <strong>in</strong>clude sections on national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems<br />

<strong>in</strong> which the mechanisms for fix<strong>in</strong>g and revis<strong>in</strong>g wage floors are described by<br />

the Observatory's country experts.<br />

In sum, exist<strong>in</strong>g databases conta<strong>in</strong> statistical <strong>in</strong>formation on the bite of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> at the aggregate, national level. At the same time, they have<br />

numerous limitations: they fail to provide statistical <strong>in</strong>formation for countries<br />

with sub-national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>; they only conta<strong>in</strong> Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices that do not<br />

adjust for exist<strong>in</strong>g sub-m<strong>in</strong>ima, the impact of the tax system, or cross-country<br />

differences <strong>in</strong> the composition of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong>-wage earners; and, importantly,<br />

they do not allow to assess neither the employment spike at or near the<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage nor the shadow spike that corresponds to hypothetical<br />

<strong>in</strong>creases of the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage. In other words, these databases are useful to<br />

obta<strong>in</strong> a general impression of cross-country differences regard<strong>in</strong>g the bite of<br />

national statutory <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>, but they are less apt to further our<br />

understand<strong>in</strong>g of the impact of other types of wage floors. Crucially, they do<br />

not allow to shed light on the characteristics of the affected populations.<br />

As a consequence of these limitations, exist<strong>in</strong>g studies on <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong><br />

earners typically use micro-data from labour force surveys to elucidate<br />

questions such as the size and composition of the employment spike around<br />

the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage (Dolado et al., 1996; Mach<strong>in</strong> and Mann<strong>in</strong>g, 1997;<br />

<strong>Europe</strong>an Commission, 1998; OECD, 1998; Neumark and Wascher, 2004;<br />

Funk and Lesch, 2006). These studies reveal significant with<strong>in</strong>-country<br />

variation <strong>in</strong> the bite of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>: Funk and Lesch (2006), for <strong>in</strong>stance,<br />

report that whereas the 2004 <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage <strong>in</strong> Lithuania represented only<br />

38 per cent of average <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> the economy as a whole, the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

<strong>in</strong> the Hotels and Restaurants Sector was as high as 61 per cent of average<br />

<strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> that sector. Similarly, <strong>in</strong> 2004 the Estonian Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex was 34 per<br />

cent for the entire economy, but 67 per cent <strong>in</strong> the Retail Sector. The bite of<br />

5. A voivodship is an adm<strong>in</strong>istrative unit of the Polish state.<br />

6. http://www.eurofound.europa.eu/eiro/structure.htm<br />

22 Report 124


the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage also differs accord<strong>in</strong>g to characteristics such as age and<br />

gender. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the figures <strong>in</strong> OECD (1998), the mid-1997 <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage <strong>in</strong> Belgium represented 49.2 per cent of full-time median earn<strong>in</strong>gs for<br />

men, but as much as 55.2 per cent for women and 66.5 per cent for employees<br />

aged 20-24 years.<br />

What is more, exist<strong>in</strong>g evidence suggests that the share of workers paid at or<br />

near <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage levels differs substantially among <strong>Europe</strong>an countries:<br />

the work force of the Netherlands, Slovenia, Sweden, or Belgium <strong>in</strong>cludes less<br />

than five per cent of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners, whereas this share lies above 10<br />

per cent <strong>in</strong> countries like France, Latvia, Lithuania, and Greece (Dolado et. al,<br />

1996; Funk and Lesch, 2006). Such <strong>in</strong>ternational comparisons are, however,<br />

extremely rare and outdated <strong>in</strong> light of recent developments <strong>in</strong> many<br />

<strong>Europe</strong>an economies. Notably a systematic comparison of the impact of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> Western, Central, and Eastern <strong>Europe</strong> is currently not<br />

available. The objective of this report is to fill this knowledge gap.<br />

The results presented <strong>in</strong> Section 3 are based on different data sources. While<br />

most of the qualitative <strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage system has been<br />

collected from the above mentioned sources (the ILO, WSI and EIRO data<br />

have been the most useful <strong>in</strong> this regard), most of the quantitative<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation has been drawn from a representative panel with harmonised<br />

mirco-data, namely the latest (2008) update of the <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>Union</strong> Statistics<br />

on Income and Liv<strong>in</strong>g Conditions (SILC). This extensive EU dataset allows to<br />

compute the bite of the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage and to identify various characteristics<br />

of the <strong>in</strong>dividuals receiv<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage. In particular, the SILC<br />

conta<strong>in</strong>s detailed <strong>in</strong>formation on sectors and occupations that allows to<br />

estimate the impact of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> countries that do not fix <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong> at the national level (such as Italy), or <strong>in</strong> countries with sub-m<strong>in</strong>ima for<br />

younger employees (such as Belgium and the Czech Republic). Unfortunately,<br />

the German DE-SILC data does not allow to identify the region <strong>in</strong> which an<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividual works (to our knowledge, the correspond<strong>in</strong>g NUTS 1 variable is not<br />

dissem<strong>in</strong>ated by the German statistical authorities due to data protection<br />

issues). S<strong>in</strong>ce the regional variation <strong>in</strong> the German wage distribution is<br />

particularly strong, we decided to compute all <strong>in</strong>dicators with data from the<br />

German socio-economic panel. Incidentally, the SOEP happens to be very<br />

similar to the SILC <strong>in</strong> terms of sample design and data collection procedures<br />

- some commentators even argue that the SOEP is more comparable to other<br />

EU-SILC samples than the DE-SILC (Frick and Krell, 2009; see also the<br />

discussion <strong>in</strong> Kampelmann and Rycx, forthcom<strong>in</strong>g).<br />

2.4 Typology of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

One of the ma<strong>in</strong> challenges that have to be addressed <strong>in</strong> any comparative<br />

study on <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> is the <strong>in</strong>stitutional diversity between countries. The<br />

problem lies <strong>in</strong> the fact that no two countries are identical with respect to the<br />

labour market <strong>in</strong>stitutions that <strong>in</strong>fluence how <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> are<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>ed, adjusted, implemented, monitored, etc.<br />

Report 124<br />

23


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

A rather basic solution to this problem is to limit the analysis to countries with<br />

relatively similar systems. This approach has been adopted by most exist<strong>in</strong>g<br />

studies that focus exclusively on countries <strong>in</strong> which a national statutory<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage is determ<strong>in</strong>ed by some centralised mechanism such as a<br />

government agency (like <strong>in</strong> the UK) or a tripartite commission that negotiates<br />

a national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage through collective agreement (like <strong>in</strong> Poland).<br />

Countries whose system does not def<strong>in</strong>e a statutory <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage at the<br />

national level (like Italy, Germany, or the Scand<strong>in</strong>avian countries) are<br />

typically not considered <strong>in</strong> these studies.<br />

We argue that this approach is not satisfactory if our task is to reflect how<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> affect the labour market <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> as a whole, and not only<br />

<strong>in</strong> countries that happen to share a relatively similar <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage system.<br />

As a matter of fact, focus<strong>in</strong>g only on national statutory <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong><br />

completely misses other <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> mechanisms, such as sectoral or<br />

regional determ<strong>in</strong>ation of wage floors. For <strong>in</strong>stance, it is clear that the lowest<br />

tariffs guaranteed by collective agreements typically function as effective<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> and should therefore enter the scope of this study. Or, as the<br />

<strong>in</strong>troduction to the WSI <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> data base puts it, "Tariflöhne s<strong>in</strong>d<br />

M<strong>in</strong>destlöhne". The follow<strong>in</strong>g quote taken from a typical Belgian collective<br />

agreement also illustrates that the lowest <strong>wages</strong> agreed <strong>in</strong> collective<br />

barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g are effective <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>:<br />

"Ce salaire horaire <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> correspond au niveau le plus bas<br />

applicable, à savoir à la fonction de manoeuvre ord<strong>in</strong>aire."<br />

(CCT relative au salaire horaire <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> conclue le 27 ju<strong>in</strong><br />

2007 au se<strong>in</strong> de la Commission Paritaire de l'<strong>in</strong>dustrie<br />

chimique.)<br />

In order to br<strong>in</strong>g countries <strong>in</strong> which <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> are set at the <strong>in</strong>franational<br />

level back <strong>in</strong>to the picture, we propose a straightforward typology<br />

that has both <strong>in</strong>tuitive appeal and fits well to the empirical results presented<br />

<strong>in</strong> Section 3. Our typology dist<strong>in</strong>guishes between two types of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

systems:<br />

— Type I: the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage that applies to most workers and employees<br />

is determ<strong>in</strong>ed through the decision of a governmental agency or<br />

collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g at the national level. Further differentiation of this<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage plays a m<strong>in</strong>or role <strong>in</strong> countries that belong to this type.<br />

In its ideal-typical form, such a system leads to a clean cut <strong>in</strong> the wage<br />

distribution at the level of the national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage, which is why we<br />

refer to this k<strong>in</strong>d of set-up as a "clean-cut system"<br />

— Type II: the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage that applies to most workers and employees<br />

is determ<strong>in</strong>ed at the <strong>in</strong>fra-national level, for <strong>in</strong>stance <strong>in</strong> sector or regional<br />

negotiations. The ideal-type of this system <strong>in</strong>cludes many different<br />

m<strong>in</strong>ima so that no clear truncation is visible at any particular po<strong>in</strong>t of the<br />

wage distribution. Due to the multiplicity of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>, we refer to<br />

this type as "complex system".<br />

24 Report 124


<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

In practice, most countries conta<strong>in</strong> elements of both types of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

systems. For example, a given country may fix <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> for some<br />

category of workers at the national level through a statutory wage floor, while<br />

the m<strong>in</strong>ima for other categories of workers are renegotiated at the sector or<br />

regional level. It is nevertheless possible to classify most <strong>Europe</strong>an countries<br />

<strong>in</strong>to one of the two types, as is done <strong>in</strong> Table 1. As a general rule, it is clear that<br />

complex systems are dom<strong>in</strong>ated by collectively barga<strong>in</strong>ed wage floors<br />

whereas <strong>in</strong> clean-cut systems statutory m<strong>in</strong>ima prevail (see also Table 2 <strong>in</strong><br />

Section 3).<br />

Table 1 <strong>Europe</strong>an countries accord<strong>in</strong>g to a typology of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems<br />

Nordic<br />

Anglo-Saxon<br />

Western Cont<strong>in</strong>ental<br />

Southern<br />

Central and Eastern<br />

Type A countries<br />

("clean-cut systems")<br />

United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, Ireland<br />

Luxembourg, Netherlands<br />

Cyprus, Spa<strong>in</strong>, Portugal, Greece<br />

Czech Republic, Bulgaria, Estonia,<br />

Hungary, Lithuania, Latvia, Poland,<br />

Romania, Slovenia<br />

Type B countries<br />

("complex systems")<br />

F<strong>in</strong>land, Denmark, Norway, Sweden,<br />

Iceland<br />

Austria, Belgium, Germany<br />

Italy<br />

Our typology reveals a geographical stratification of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems.<br />

All of the Nordic countries operate <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage system that are "complex",<br />

i.e. many different m<strong>in</strong>ima co-exist side by side. In order to know which<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage applies to an <strong>in</strong>dividual worker, it is typically necessary to<br />

obta<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation on her sector of activity, occupation, age, tenure, and<br />

residence. By contrast, the new Members States from Central and Eastern<br />

<strong>Europe</strong> have "clean-cut" systems, i.e. the wage distribution is truncated by a<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage that applies to most workers. The Anglo-Saxon countries <strong>in</strong><br />

our sample (United K<strong>in</strong>gdom and Ireland) also established systems that apply<br />

if not a s<strong>in</strong>gle, but nevertheless a small number of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> at the<br />

national level. Western Cont<strong>in</strong>ental and Southern <strong>Europe</strong> cannot be classified<br />

<strong>in</strong>to one of the two types: while Austria, Belgium, Germany, Greece, and Italy<br />

have complex <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems, Luxembourg, the Netherlands,<br />

Cyprus, Spa<strong>in</strong>, and Portugal resemble more the clean-cut type.<br />

Report 124<br />

25


3. M<strong>in</strong>imum <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong>:<br />

empirical results<br />

In the framework of this report it was not possible to study all of the countries<br />

listed <strong>in</strong> Table 1. This is particularly true for the set of countries with complex<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems because the computation of employment effects and<br />

the socio-demographic composition of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners requires<br />

collect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation on the array of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> that apply <strong>in</strong> each of<br />

these countries. We therefore chose to focus on a limited set of countries that<br />

nevertheless a) reflect the <strong>in</strong>ternational diversity of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems,<br />

i.e. conta<strong>in</strong>s both types of systems described <strong>in</strong> the previous section; b) strikes<br />

a geographic balance between the different <strong>Europe</strong>an sub-regions (Nordic,<br />

Anglo-Saxon, Western-Cont<strong>in</strong>ental, Southern, Central and Eastern <strong>Europe</strong>);<br />

and f<strong>in</strong>ally c) have a sufficiently large EU-SILC sample to allow for statistical<br />

<strong>in</strong>ference. After consultations with experts from the <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>Union</strong><br />

Institute <strong>in</strong> October 2011, we opted to focus <strong>in</strong> the empirical section of this<br />

report on the follow<strong>in</strong>g countries: Belgium, Bulgaria, Germany, Hungary,<br />

Ireland, Poland, Romania, Spa<strong>in</strong>, and the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom. Given the absence<br />

of important countries <strong>in</strong> this sample (France and the Scand<strong>in</strong>avian countries<br />

could not be treated at this po<strong>in</strong>t), we hope to be able to extend this selection<br />

to a wider set of countries <strong>in</strong> the near future (see also the suggestions for<br />

further research <strong>in</strong> Section 4). The presentation of the empirical results on<br />

these countries is divided <strong>in</strong>to two parts: Section 3.1 presents qualitative<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems and documents the diversity of<br />

<strong>Europe</strong>an countries with respect to the way <strong>in</strong> which <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> are<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>ed, extended, and differentiated <strong>in</strong> each of the countries <strong>in</strong> our<br />

sample. The quantitative results based on the EU-SILC and GSOEP data are<br />

presented <strong>in</strong> Section 3.2.<br />

3.1 The qualitative dimension: the <strong>Europe</strong>an diversity<br />

of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems<br />

The qualitative data on national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems has been handpicked<br />

from the major databases mentioned <strong>in</strong> Section 2, ma<strong>in</strong>ly the ILO<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage database, the country reports published by the <strong>Europe</strong>an<br />

Industrial Relations Observatory, the database on collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

agreements by the Belgian M<strong>in</strong>istry of Employment, and the WSI <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage database. For each of the n<strong>in</strong>e countries <strong>in</strong> our sample, Table 2 presents<br />

a) the type of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage system; b) the mechanism with which <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong> are determ<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> each country; c) a description of exist<strong>in</strong>g extension<br />

mechanism; d) if applicable, a list of categories of workers that are exempted<br />

from the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage; e) a description of the <strong>in</strong>fra-national differentiation<br />

26 Report 124


<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> accord<strong>in</strong>g to categories such as age, occupation,<br />

education, etc; f) for Type I countries, we report the the level of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage <strong>in</strong> 2007 <strong>in</strong> the national currency; and g) the typical length of the work<br />

week (or month) to which the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage applies.<br />

Table 2 illustrates the difference between the ideal-typical dist<strong>in</strong>ctions we<br />

def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the previous Section and empirical <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems. In<br />

practice, only Hungary and Romania comes close to a "pure" clean-cut system<br />

<strong>in</strong> which only one national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage is b<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g for all employees. All<br />

other countries have systems <strong>in</strong> which some employees are exempted from<br />

statutory m<strong>in</strong>ima; <strong>in</strong> addition, most countries differentiate the national<br />

m<strong>in</strong>ima accord<strong>in</strong>g to age or occupational categories. This be<strong>in</strong>g said, we argue<br />

that despite these deviations from the ideal-type of "clean-cut systems", the<br />

systems <strong>in</strong> the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, Ireland, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Cyprus,<br />

Spa<strong>in</strong>, Portugal, Czech Republic, Bulgaria, Estonia, Hungary, Lithuania,<br />

Latvia, Poland, Romania, and Slovenia are nevertheless sufficiently close to<br />

be classified with<strong>in</strong> this type.<br />

3.2 The quantitative dimension: employment<br />

<strong>in</strong>cidence, Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices and characteristics of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners (and their households)<br />

Turn<strong>in</strong>g to the quantitative dimension of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems, we first<br />

report the levels of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> that apply <strong>in</strong> each of the n<strong>in</strong>e countries<br />

<strong>in</strong> our sample. Although most comparative studies focus only on one<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage per country, we have documented <strong>in</strong> the previous Section that<br />

even countries that resemble a clean-cut system typically def<strong>in</strong>e a range of<br />

different m<strong>in</strong>ima accord<strong>in</strong>g to categories such as age, education, tenure, etc<br />

(see Table 2). We have dealt with the differentiation of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong><br />

Type I countries by show<strong>in</strong>g not only the lowest and highest m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong> each<br />

country, but also by calculat<strong>in</strong>g an average of the different exist<strong>in</strong>g rates.<br />

Given that the EU-SILC data conta<strong>in</strong>s socio-demographic <strong>in</strong>formation on<br />

each <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong> the sample, we were able to assign the correspond<strong>in</strong>g<br />

categorical <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage to each <strong>in</strong>dividual. The average <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage <strong>in</strong><br />

Table 3 below are therefore weighted averages that reflect the distribution of<br />

total employment accord<strong>in</strong>g to the different <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage rates that coexist<br />

<strong>in</strong> each country. After convert<strong>in</strong>g the national currency amounts for 2007 (the<br />

latest available wave of the EU-SILC was collected <strong>in</strong> 2008 and conta<strong>in</strong>s<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation on earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> 2007), Table 1 illustrates the considerable<br />

diversity of absolute levels of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong>. Among the Type I<br />

countries, the range of m<strong>in</strong>ima starts from 53 cents per hour <strong>in</strong> Bulgaria and<br />

extends to 8.37 euros <strong>in</strong> Ireland.<br />

Our sample also conta<strong>in</strong>s two Type II countries, namely Belgium and<br />

Germany. In light of the <strong>in</strong>stitutional set-up of their respective <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage systems, the computation of the lowest, highest, and average <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage is considerably more difficult <strong>in</strong> these two countries. Indeed, this<br />

Report 124<br />

27


Table 2 Characteristics of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems <strong>in</strong> selected <strong>Europe</strong>an countries<br />

Weekly full time<br />

work<strong>in</strong>g hours 2<br />

Level of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage <strong>in</strong> 2007 2<br />

Differentiation<br />

Exemptions<br />

Extension mechanism<br />

Determ<strong>in</strong>ation of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong>1 Type of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage system<br />

Country<br />

François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

38 hours per week,<br />

165 hours per month<br />

1258,91 (until 1/4/07)<br />

and 1283,91 euros per<br />

month (after 1/4/07)<br />

Reduced rates for 16-20 year old<br />

(plus seniority rules for 21.5 and<br />

22.5 year-olds) (CCT N° 43, 50)<br />

Public sector<br />

employees and<br />

apprentices (Funk and<br />

Lesch, 2005)<br />

Collective agreements are<br />

extended to all workers<br />

by Royal Decree<br />

Collective agreement<br />

(<strong>in</strong>terprofessional <strong>in</strong> Conseils<br />

central de l'économie; sectoral <strong>in</strong><br />

Commission Paritaire)<br />

complex<br />

Belgium<br />

28 Report 124<br />

40 hours per week,<br />

173 hours per month<br />

180 lew per month<br />

Dur<strong>in</strong>g an apprentice's tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

period, which cannot exceed 6<br />

months, an apprentice's<br />

remuneration may not be less<br />

than 90% of the national<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage rate. (ILO<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage database)<br />

No exemptions (ILO<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

database)<br />

erga omnes<br />

Government sets the national<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage rate by Decree<br />

clean-cut<br />

Bulgaria<br />

Differ across firms,<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustries, regions:<br />

35 - 42 hours per week<br />

—<br />

Collective agreements often<br />

differentiate accord<strong>in</strong>g to age.<br />

Unless collective<br />

agreement is extended<br />

or AEntG applies, only<br />

trade workers <strong>in</strong> firms<br />

bound to collective<br />

agreements<br />

(tarifgebundene<br />

Unternehmen) are<br />

covered<br />

erga omnes only if<br />

government applies § 5<br />

Tarifvertragsgesetz or<br />

AEntG (WSI-M<strong>in</strong>destlohndatenbank)<br />

Collective agreements<br />

negotiated at different levels:<br />

local, regional, branch, etc<br />

complex<br />

Germany<br />

40 hours per week,<br />

173 hours per month<br />

65500 for<strong>in</strong>t per month<br />

No differentiation (Funk and<br />

Lesch, 2005)<br />

No exemptions (Funk<br />

and Lesch, 2005)<br />

erga omnes<br />

Government with the agreement<br />

of National Council for the<br />

Reconciliation of the Interest,<br />

collective agreements can<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

clean-cut<br />

Hungary<br />

39 hours per week,<br />

169 hours per month<br />

8.30 euros per hour<br />

(until 1/7/07) 8.65<br />

(after 1/7/07)<br />

Lower rates for employees under<br />

18 and employees <strong>in</strong> education<br />

(<strong>Europe</strong>an Industrial Relations<br />

Observatory)<br />

No exemptions (Funk<br />

and Lesch, 2005)<br />

erga omnes<br />

National <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage rate set<br />

<strong>in</strong> an Order made by the M<strong>in</strong>ister<br />

for Enterprise, <strong>Trade</strong> and<br />

Employment<br />

clean-cut<br />

Ireland


Table 2 Characteristics of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems <strong>in</strong> selected <strong>Europe</strong>an countries (cont<strong>in</strong>ued)<br />

Weekly full time<br />

work<strong>in</strong>g hours 2<br />

Level of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage <strong>in</strong> 2007 2<br />

Differentiation<br />

Exemptions<br />

Extension mechanism<br />

Determ<strong>in</strong>ation of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong> 1<br />

Type of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage system<br />

Country<br />

40 hours per week,<br />

173 hours per month<br />

936 zloty per month<br />

Lower rates for employees who<br />

enter the labour market (80%<br />

first year, 90% second year)<br />

No exemptions.<br />

erga omnes<br />

Statutory <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

negotiated <strong>in</strong> Tripartite<br />

Commission<br />

clean-cut<br />

Poland<br />

39.2 hours per week,<br />

170 hours per month<br />

390 lei per month<br />

Different rates accord<strong>in</strong>g to<br />

educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment<br />

(<strong>Europe</strong>an Industrial Relations<br />

Observatory)<br />

No exemptions.<br />

erga omnes<br />

The government sets a national<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage rate follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

consultation with the social<br />

partners<br />

clean-cut<br />

Romania<br />

38 hours per week,<br />

165 hours per month<br />

570.60 euros per<br />

month<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum wage for tra<strong>in</strong>ees<br />

cannot be less than 70, 80 and<br />

90% of the <strong>in</strong>ter-profession<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage for the first,<br />

second and third year<br />

(respectively) of validity of the<br />

contract. (ILO <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

database); Reduced rate of<br />

66.7 % (Funk and Lesch, 2005)<br />

No exemptions.<br />

erga omnes<br />

Government annually fixes the<br />

<strong>in</strong>teroccupational <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage by Royal Decree follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a period of consultation with the<br />

most representative trade unions<br />

and employers' associations<br />

clean-cut<br />

Spa<strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

38 hours per week,<br />

165 hours per month<br />

5.35 pounds per hour<br />

(until 1/10/07), 5.52<br />

pounds per hour (after<br />

1/10/07)<br />

Reduced rates for younger<br />

employees, certa<strong>in</strong> occupations,<br />

and employees <strong>in</strong> tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

(<strong>Europe</strong>an Industrial Relations<br />

Observatory)<br />

No exemptions.<br />

erga omnes<br />

The Secretary of State<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>es the national<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

clean-cut<br />

United<br />

K<strong>in</strong>gdom<br />

Notes<br />

1 ILO <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage database<br />

2 WSI-M<strong>in</strong>destlohndatenbank<br />

Report 124<br />

29


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation first has to be hand-collected from collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

agreements: <strong>in</strong> Belgium, these are the Conventions Collectives de Travail that<br />

are negotiated <strong>in</strong> more or less irregular <strong>in</strong>tervals with<strong>in</strong> the different<br />

Commissions Paritaires; <strong>in</strong> Germany, the data had to be collected from the<br />

Tarifverträge that are negotiated among the social partners at the regional<br />

and sectoral level 7 . We have notably collected <strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong> from collective agreements that were signed <strong>in</strong> 2007, thereby<br />

circumvent<strong>in</strong>g the issue of older agreements that might still be b<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g but<br />

subject to <strong>in</strong>dex<strong>in</strong>g (which is notably <strong>in</strong> Belgium a wide-spread phenomenon).<br />

For the case of Belgium, we collected <strong>in</strong>formation for around 150 Commission<br />

or Sous-Commission Paritaires. For Germany, recorded the 2007 <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> more than 70 Tarifbranchen. In light of the marked wage <strong>in</strong>equality<br />

between the Länder of the former DDR and BRD, we <strong>in</strong>cluded both the level<br />

of the lowest wage category <strong>in</strong> both East and West Germany, which means<br />

that we have collected <strong>in</strong>formation on around 150 different m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong><br />

Germany and <strong>in</strong> Belgium, respectively. 8 As a consequence, the average<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> Table 3 reflect the range of sectoral (and regional) m<strong>in</strong>ima<br />

and the distribution of total employment among these different m<strong>in</strong>ima. 9<br />

As for the results for our type II countries, Table 3 shows that the range<br />

between the lowest and the highest <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage is considerably greater <strong>in</strong><br />

Germany than <strong>in</strong> Belgium: the German lowest <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>in</strong> 2007 amounts to<br />

only 3.91 euros and the highest to 12.21 euros. In Belgium, no sectoral<br />

agreement is allowed to undercut the <strong>in</strong>terprofessional <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage,<br />

which means that <strong>in</strong> 2007 no sectoral <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> could be fixed below<br />

7.80 euros. The highest wage floor negotiated dur<strong>in</strong>g 2007 was equal to<br />

13.21 euros. The weighted averages of sectoral m<strong>in</strong>ima were 9.22 and<br />

7.63 euros <strong>in</strong> Belgium and Germany, respectively.<br />

As discussed <strong>in</strong> Section 2, absolute levels of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> are not directly<br />

comparable across countries with different wage distributions. The<br />

computation of a Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex is one way to take differences <strong>in</strong> the overall<br />

shape of the wage distribution <strong>in</strong>to account by compar<strong>in</strong>g the exist<strong>in</strong>g<br />

national m<strong>in</strong>ima to the correspond median wage. This be<strong>in</strong>g said, we have<br />

seen that only very few countries operate a <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage system <strong>in</strong> which a<br />

s<strong>in</strong>gle rate applies to all employees; <strong>in</strong> practice, many different rates - and<br />

many different Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices - co-exist <strong>in</strong> each country. As a consequence, the<br />

Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices shown <strong>in</strong> Table 3 are averages of the multiple Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices <strong>in</strong><br />

7. Although clearly relevant for empirical <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> most of the countries <strong>in</strong> our study, after<br />

consultations with experts from the <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>Union</strong> Institute <strong>in</strong> October 2011, we<br />

decided to ignore any further renegotiation of m<strong>in</strong>ima that occurs at the firm level.<br />

8. We would like to thank the WSI, and <strong>in</strong> particular Re<strong>in</strong>hard Bisp<strong>in</strong>ck, for the extremely<br />

helpful assistance <strong>in</strong> collect<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> from German Tariff contracts <strong>in</strong> 2007.<br />

9. Unfortunately, it was not possible for the case of Germany to calculate the employment weight<br />

for each Tarifbranche because the SOEP data on sector of activity is based on the NACE and<br />

not on the system of Tarifbranchen. The weighted average is therefore based on the<br />

distribution of employment among NACE and the correspondence between NACE 2-digit<br />

sectors and Traifbranchen. More detailed <strong>in</strong>formation on the weight<strong>in</strong>g procedure can be<br />

obta<strong>in</strong>ed from the authors.<br />

30 Report 124


<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

each country. Like for the case of the average <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage, the average<br />

Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex has been weighted for the distribution of the total work force<br />

among the different <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage rates <strong>in</strong> each country. Among the Type I<br />

countries <strong>in</strong> our sample, Hungary has the highest average Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex (57.0),<br />

followed by the UK (53.2) and Ireland (52.6 per cent). Spa<strong>in</strong> has the lowest<br />

average Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>in</strong> our sample (39.3).<br />

The case of Belgium is special because the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage system <strong>in</strong> this<br />

countries def<strong>in</strong>es both a national (<strong>in</strong>terprofessional) wage floors and sector<br />

m<strong>in</strong>ima through collective agreement. The Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex that corresponds to<br />

the weighted average of the national rate was equal to 51.9 per cent <strong>in</strong> 2007.<br />

By def<strong>in</strong>ition the Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex based on the sectoral m<strong>in</strong>ima is higher than the<br />

national Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex and amounted to 59.6 per cent. In Germany, only<br />

sectoral <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> and Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices can be computed. The weighted<br />

average of the latter was 57.8 per cent <strong>in</strong> 2007.<br />

Statistics like the average <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage and the average Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex convey<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation about the absolute and relative value of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong><br />

monetary terms. But it is also extremely important to assess the size of the<br />

population to which these rates apply, i.e. to calculate the employment spike<br />

created by exist<strong>in</strong>g wage m<strong>in</strong>ima. For each of the countries <strong>in</strong> our sample, we<br />

have therefore marked all <strong>in</strong>dividual whose hourly wage is sufficiently close to<br />

the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage that applies to the <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong> question (tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to<br />

account her age, tenure, occupation, sector of activity, etc). Follow<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

standard practice <strong>in</strong> the literature, we counted <strong>in</strong>dividuals as <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

earners if their hourly earn<strong>in</strong>gs did not exceed the correspond<strong>in</strong>g rate by<br />

more than 5 per cent. This marg<strong>in</strong> is required to account for the measurement<br />

error <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>in</strong>dividual earn<strong>in</strong>gs (our sample relies on<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation collected via household <strong>in</strong>terviews). It should also be noted that<br />

many <strong>in</strong>dividuals reported hourly earn<strong>in</strong>gs that lie below the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

that applies to them. This might be due to several causes, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g<br />

measurement errors and non-compliance with <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage laws.<br />

Turn<strong>in</strong>g to the results for the national employment spike, it is not surpris<strong>in</strong>g<br />

that the countries with the highest average Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex also display the<br />

greatest quantities of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners: <strong>in</strong> Hungary, as much as 11.5<br />

per cent of workers are paid at or below their <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage; <strong>in</strong> the United<br />

K<strong>in</strong>gdom this figure equals 9.5 and <strong>in</strong> Ireland 9.2 per cent. On the other end<br />

of the spectrum, Spa<strong>in</strong> not only has the lowest Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex but also the<br />

smallest employment spike <strong>in</strong> our sample (3.8 per cent).<br />

The employment spike <strong>in</strong> Germany is measured at 19.0 and therefore appears<br />

to be particularly high. This figure, however, should be <strong>in</strong>terpreted with care.<br />

Most importantly, one has to keep <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d that the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> rates on the<br />

basis of which this figure has been calculated are not necessarily b<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g for<br />

all <strong>in</strong>dividuals - this is only the case <strong>in</strong> sectors <strong>in</strong> which the German<br />

government decides to apply erga omnes legislation. In all other sectors, only<br />

workers <strong>in</strong> firms that are bound to collective agreements (tarifgebundene<br />

Unternehmen) are covered by exist<strong>in</strong>g rates. As a consequence, the<br />

Report 124<br />

31


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

employment spike of 19.0 per cent should be <strong>in</strong>terpreted as the share of the<br />

work force that <strong>earns</strong> hourly <strong>wages</strong> at or below the applicable <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> rates<br />

if the government extended the collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g agreements <strong>in</strong> all<br />

sectors. S<strong>in</strong>ce not all workers are covered by collective agreements, the actual<br />

figures are arguably lower than the 19 percent shown <strong>in</strong> the table. In 2010, the<br />

sector-level tariff coverage <strong>in</strong> West Germany was 56 and <strong>in</strong> East Germany 38<br />

per cent; a first rough estimate of the actual employment spike would<br />

therefore be closer to 10 than to 20 per cent <strong>in</strong> light of observed coverage<br />

rates. This be<strong>in</strong>g said, accord<strong>in</strong>g to the WSI CB archive and personal<br />

communication from an expert of the <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>Union</strong> Institute, <strong>in</strong><br />

Germany the effective impact of collectively agreed m<strong>in</strong>ima is likely to extend<br />

to firms that are not directly bound by collective agreements. Notably <strong>in</strong> West<br />

Germany, as many as half of the non-bound employers appear to implement<br />

wage policies that are directly <strong>in</strong>fluenced by collectively barga<strong>in</strong>ed wage<br />

floors. 10 Given that numerous German firms therefore apply collectively<br />

negotiated <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> even though that they are bound to do so, the<br />

effective employment spike is arguably substantially higher.<br />

For the case of Belgium, it is <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g to note that the employment spike<br />

based on the national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage is considerably lower than the more<br />

realistic figure calculated on the basis of sectoral m<strong>in</strong>ima. Indeed, <strong>in</strong> 2007 the<br />

share of workers that earn <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong>creases from 6.9 to 11.4 per cent.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, one might also be <strong>in</strong>terested by the size of the population that is<br />

remunerated below certa<strong>in</strong> threshold values, for <strong>in</strong>stance when assess<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

impact of a hypothetical rise <strong>in</strong> the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage (or the Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex) to a<br />

given level. Such a “shadow spike” can yield <strong>in</strong>formation on the bite of the<br />

hypothetical rise <strong>in</strong> the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage by <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g how many and what<br />

types of employees would be affected <strong>in</strong> such a scenario. It should be noted,<br />

however, that the “shadow spike” can differ substantially from the<br />

employment spike that will be observed if the hypothetical <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease is actually implemented. The difference between the two spikes<br />

might stem from several factors: a higher <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage might attract new<br />

employees <strong>in</strong>to the labour force, thereby chang<strong>in</strong>g its socio-demographic<br />

composition; conversely, some employees <strong>in</strong> the shadow spike might be laid<br />

off if the higher <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage renders their employment unprofitable.<br />

At the request of the <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>Union</strong> Institute, we have calculated the<br />

shadow employment spike that corresponds to a policy that would fix a s<strong>in</strong>gle<br />

national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage at 50 per cent of the medium wage <strong>in</strong> each of the<br />

countries <strong>in</strong> our sample. Given that the average Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>in</strong> some of the<br />

countries lies currently above this level, such a policy is associated with<br />

smaller shadow employment spikes <strong>in</strong> these countries: this is the case for<br />

Hungary, Ireland, the UK, Belgium, and Germany (see Table 3). By contrast,<br />

10. The effect of collectively negotiated wage floors on firms that are not bound by collective<br />

agreements is conceptually similar to the so-called "knock-on" or "ripple" effects of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

<strong>wages</strong> that have been observed <strong>in</strong> different countries. In both cases, <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> impact<br />

on <strong>wages</strong> paid to <strong>in</strong>dividuals that are not directly covered by exist<strong>in</strong>g wage floors.<br />

32 Report 124


Table 3 Level of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>, share of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners, and Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices per country (2007)<br />

Share of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners accord<strong>in</strong>g to different<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (per cent)<br />

Employment-weighted Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex accord<strong>in</strong>g<br />

to different <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (per cent) 2<br />

Level of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (current euros)<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum wage<br />

equal to 50 per cent<br />

of median wage<br />

Sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

National<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

Sector <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

National <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

Employmentweighted<br />

average<br />

of m<strong>in</strong>ima2 Highest<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

Lowest<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

Obs.<br />

TYPE I COUNTRIES<br />

12.2<br />

4.7<br />

—<br />

—<br />

5.8<br />

—<br />

—<br />

41.0<br />

57.0<br />

0.53<br />

1.51<br />

0.53<br />

1.51<br />

0.48<br />

1.51<br />

3904<br />

6513<br />

Bulgaria<br />

Hungary<br />

8.8<br />

11.5<br />

9.2<br />

—<br />

—<br />

—<br />

—<br />

52.6<br />

47.5<br />

8.37<br />

1.42<br />

8.48<br />

1.43<br />

5.93<br />

1.14<br />

3361<br />

10.4<br />

8.3<br />

8.9<br />

4.9<br />

10452<br />

5055<br />

—<br />

—<br />

—<br />

—<br />

44.4<br />

39.9<br />

0.69<br />

3.41<br />

0.69<br />

3.46<br />

0.69<br />

2.42<br />

7.9<br />

7.7<br />

—<br />

3.8<br />

9.5<br />

—<br />

53.2<br />

7.78<br />

7.86<br />

4.85<br />

11327<br />

7029<br />

Ireland<br />

Poland<br />

Romania<br />

Spa<strong>in</strong><br />

United K<strong>in</strong>gdom<br />

TYPE II COUNTRIES<br />

6.6<br />

11.4<br />

14.3<br />

19.0 3<br />

6.9<br />

—<br />

59.6<br />

57.8<br />

51.9<br />

—<br />

9.22<br />

7.63<br />

13.21<br />

12.21<br />

7.80<br />

3.91<br />

5100<br />

8833<br />

Belgium<br />

Germany<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

Notes<br />

1 Germany SOEP, EU-SILC for all other countries<br />

2 Weight<strong>in</strong>g variables depend on differentiation of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>; employment weighted by sector (and region for Germany)<br />

3 Figure is not corrected for <strong>in</strong>complete collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g coverage at the sector level (see explanation <strong>in</strong> the text).<br />

Report 124<br />

33


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

the shadow employment spike is higher than the actual employment spike <strong>in</strong><br />

Bulgaria, Poland, Romania, and Spa<strong>in</strong>.<br />

3.2.1 Graphical analysis<br />

A complementary way to shed light on the <strong>in</strong>ternational variations among<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems is to depict the exist<strong>in</strong>g wage floors with the help of<br />

distributional graphs. This exercise is particularly salient as it allows to<br />

visualize the dist<strong>in</strong>ction between Type I and Type II countries that we<br />

<strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong> Section 2.4.<br />

Figures 1 through 4 plot exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> as th<strong>in</strong> vertical l<strong>in</strong>es onto<br />

the national wage distribution <strong>in</strong> 2007. The difference between Type I<br />

countries (Bulgaria and Hungary) and Type II countries (Belgium and<br />

Germany) comes out very clearly on these graphs: the two former countries<br />

display a clean cut that truncates the wage distribution at the level of the<br />

(national) <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>; the employment spike around the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage is clearly visible <strong>in</strong> both countries. This holds also for the other Type I<br />

countries whose wage distributions can be found <strong>in</strong> Annex A.<br />

By contrast, the shape of the lower tail of the wage distributions of Belgium<br />

and Germany are much more gradual and reflect the existence of an array of<br />

different sectoral m<strong>in</strong>ima. This be<strong>in</strong>g said, it should be noted that even <strong>in</strong><br />

Type II countries each exist<strong>in</strong>g wage floor also creates a truncated wage<br />

Figure 1 Wage distribution and m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong> Bulgaria (2007)<br />

0 2 4 6 8<br />

percent<br />

Source: BU-SILC; current 2007 euros; th<strong>in</strong> vertical l<strong>in</strong>es represent levels of national m<strong>in</strong>ima (differentiated by educational<br />

activity and job tenure).<br />

34 Report 124<br />

Bulgaria (2007)<br />

0 1 2 3 4 5<br />

gross hourly wage (euros)


distribution. However <strong>in</strong> order to reveal this phenomenon graphically, it is<br />

necessary to disaggregate the overall population and plot the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

onto the sub-population to which it applies (we will come back to this issue <strong>in</strong><br />

the sector by sector analysis below).<br />

Figure 2 Wage distribution and m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong> Hungary (2007)<br />

0 5 10 15<br />

percent<br />

Hungary (2007)<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

0 5 10 15<br />

gross hourly wage (euros)<br />

Source: HU-SILC; current 2007 euros; th<strong>in</strong> vertical l<strong>in</strong>es represent level of national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong>.<br />

Figure 3 Wage distribution and m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong> Belgium (2007)<br />

0 2 4 6 8 10<br />

percent<br />

Belgium (2007)<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50<br />

gross hourly wage (euros)<br />

Source: BE-SILC; current 2007 euros; th<strong>in</strong> vertical l<strong>in</strong>es represent levels of m<strong>in</strong>ima (differentiated by sector).<br />

Report 124<br />

35


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

Figure 4 Wage distribution and m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong> Germany (2007)<br />

0 2 4 6 8<br />

percent<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50<br />

gross hourly wage (euros)<br />

Source: SOEP; current 2007 euros; th<strong>in</strong> vertical l<strong>in</strong>es represent levels of m<strong>in</strong>ima (differentiated by sector and region).<br />

3.2.2 Individual and job characteristics of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

earners<br />

So far we presented <strong>in</strong>formation on the size of the employment spike around<br />

wage m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong> general. We now turn to the composition of the population of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners. This will be done by compar<strong>in</strong>g them to the rest of<br />

the labour force with respect to a range of socio-demographic and job<br />

characteristics.<br />

Table 4 conta<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>in</strong>dividual characteristics, namely on age,<br />

sex, and educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment. Although there is some diversity among the<br />

different countries, <strong>in</strong> all of them the population of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners is<br />

similar <strong>in</strong> that it is characterised by:<br />

— a lower average age;<br />

— on average more female employment;<br />

— lower levels of educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment than workers with higher <strong>wages</strong>.<br />

Table 4 also shows the standard deviation associated with the average age and<br />

proportion of female workers that allow to compute whether the observed<br />

differences between the two sub-populations are statistically significant <strong>in</strong> the<br />

different countries of our sample.<br />

As for the job characteristics, Table 5 compares the two sub-populations with<br />

respect to the share of temporary work contracts and the <strong>in</strong>cidence of part<br />

time jobs. The latter has been def<strong>in</strong>ed as employments whose average weekly<br />

36 Report 124<br />

Germany (2007)


work hours do not exceed 35 hours. Aga<strong>in</strong>, we observe a clear difference<br />

between the two sub-populations <strong>in</strong> all countries. In particular, the group of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> earners stands out as conta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g:<br />

— a considerably higher share of employees with temporary work contracts;<br />

— a higher share of part time employment than the sub-population with<br />

higher <strong>wages</strong>.<br />

In light of cross-country variations <strong>in</strong> terms of the average age, education,<br />

contract type etc among the countries <strong>in</strong> our sample, it is not straightforward<br />

to assess the overall relationship between a particular <strong>in</strong>dividual or job<br />

characteristic and the probability of be<strong>in</strong>g paid at the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage. One<br />

way to compute such probabilities is to estimate a logistic model <strong>in</strong> which the<br />

likelihood of be<strong>in</strong>g paid the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage is expla<strong>in</strong>ed with the set variables<br />

shown <strong>in</strong> Table 4. This procedure allows to gauge the effect of each of the<br />

variables as a conditional probability while hold<strong>in</strong>g the other variables<br />

constant. The results of a logistic regression are presented <strong>in</strong> Section 3.3.<br />

Table 4 Individual characteristics of employees below and above <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (2007)<br />

Individual<br />

wage<br />

Educational<br />

atta<strong>in</strong>ment<br />

TYPE I COUNTRIES<br />

Bulgaria<br />

Hungary<br />

Ireland<br />

Poland<br />

Romania<br />

Spa<strong>in</strong><br />

United<br />

K<strong>in</strong>gdom<br />

TYPE II COUNTRIES<br />

Belgium<br />

Germany<br />

MW<br />

40.8<br />

(11.7)<br />

40.2<br />

(10.8)<br />

39.8<br />

(12.5)<br />

39.5<br />

(11.1)<br />

39.4<br />

(10.1)<br />

39.5<br />

(10.7)<br />

41.4<br />

(12.1)<br />

41.0<br />

(10.1)<br />

43.0<br />

(10.6)<br />

MW<br />

46.4<br />

(49.9)<br />

46.8<br />

(50.0)<br />

49.9<br />

(50.0)<br />

46.4<br />

(49.9)<br />

42.7<br />

(49.5)<br />

43.4<br />

(50.0)<br />

50.4<br />

(50.0)<br />

52.1<br />

(50.0)<br />

44.9<br />

(49.7)<br />

1<br />

41.4<br />

30.6<br />

35.6<br />

15.2<br />

30.6<br />

55.5<br />

23.5<br />

29.1<br />

21.7<br />

2<br />

54.2<br />

66.9<br />

52.3<br />

77.6<br />

66.3<br />

20.7<br />

61.8<br />

41.5<br />

68.3<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

Distribution of employees accord<strong>in</strong>g to<br />

educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment (ISCED)<br />

MW<br />

Notes<br />

1 MW are the (differentiated) national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> Type I countries and sector <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> Type II countries<br />

2 Standard errors are <strong>in</strong> parenthesis<br />

3<br />

4.4<br />

2.6<br />

12.2<br />

7.2<br />

3.1<br />

23.8<br />

14.7<br />

29.4<br />

10.1<br />

1<br />

15.1<br />

11.4<br />

22.5<br />

5.7<br />

10.6<br />

35.9<br />

9.4<br />

16.8<br />

9.0<br />

2<br />

62.3<br />

64.1<br />

36.5<br />

66.9<br />

69.1<br />

25.1<br />

54.4<br />

38.4<br />

56.1<br />

Report 124<br />

3<br />

22.6<br />

24.5<br />

41.0<br />

27.4<br />

20.3<br />

39.0<br />

36.2<br />

44.8<br />

34.9<br />

37


Bulgaria<br />

Hungary<br />

Ireland<br />

Poland<br />

Romania<br />

Spa<strong>in</strong><br />

United K<strong>in</strong>gdom<br />

Belgium<br />

Germany<br />

François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

Table 5 Job characteristics of employees below and above <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (2007)<br />

TYPE I COUNTRIES<br />

TYPE II COUNTRIES<br />

Share of employees<br />

with temporary work contracts<br />

MW<br />

5.8 (23.5)<br />

8.2 (27.4)<br />

7.1 (25.6)<br />

23.7 (42.5)<br />

2.6 (16.0)<br />

24.4 (42.9)<br />

NA<br />

6.7 (25.0)<br />

8.6 (28.0)<br />

Share of employees<br />

work<strong>in</strong>g part time<br />

MW<br />

4.1 (19.8)<br />

3.9 (19.2)<br />

33.1 (47.1)<br />

10.0 (30.0)<br />

1.2 (10.8)<br />

13.2 (33.9)<br />

25.1 (43.4)<br />

26.4 (44.1)<br />

19.3 (39.4)


<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

As for countries that have <strong>in</strong>stalled a complex system <strong>in</strong> which many<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> are def<strong>in</strong>ed at the <strong>in</strong>fra-national level, it is more difficult to<br />

calculate the employment spike at the sector level because each sector or subsector<br />

of activity has its own <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage. For the case of Germany, we<br />

even went one step further and collected <strong>in</strong>formation on separate <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

rates <strong>in</strong> East and West Germany. Unfortunately, the survey data does<br />

generally not allow to match each <strong>in</strong>dividual to the applicable <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

<strong>in</strong> light of her age, tenure, residence, occupation, sector etc. In particular, the<br />

EU-SILC conta<strong>in</strong>s only one-digit NACE codes, while the GSOEP provides<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation on two-digit sectors. However, the sectoral determ<strong>in</strong>ation of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> takes place at a more disaggregated level <strong>in</strong> both countries<br />

(e.g. three- or four-digit sectors). What is more, the <strong>Europe</strong>an nomenclature<br />

of activities used <strong>in</strong> the EU-SILC and the GSOEP does not correspond directly<br />

to the way <strong>in</strong> which the sectors are dist<strong>in</strong>guished <strong>in</strong> the Belgian Commissions<br />

Paritaires and the German Tarifbranchen. We therefore calculated the<br />

sector-level figures shown <strong>in</strong> Annex B by apply<strong>in</strong>g the follow<strong>in</strong>g procedure:<br />

we first established a correspondence between the Commissions Paritaires<br />

(for Belgium) and the Tarifbranchen (for Germany) on the one hand, and the<br />

NACE one-digit codes, on the other hand. We then calculated a weighted<br />

average of the different <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> each of the one-digit NACE<br />

sectors. As was the case for the total employment, the sectoral employment<br />

spikes shown for Germany have to be <strong>in</strong>terpreted with care. S<strong>in</strong>ce not all<br />

workers are covered by collective agreements, the actual figures are somewhat<br />

lower depend<strong>in</strong>g on the coverage <strong>in</strong> each sector (<strong>in</strong> 2010, the sector-level tariff<br />

coverage <strong>in</strong> West Germany was 56 and <strong>in</strong> East Germany 38 per cent).<br />

The Belgian system def<strong>in</strong>es both national and sectoral m<strong>in</strong>ima. Figure 5<br />

shows how the sectoral distribution of the population of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

earners changes if we def<strong>in</strong>e them <strong>in</strong> terms of the weighted average of<br />

national m<strong>in</strong>ima (panel a) or the sectoral m<strong>in</strong>ima (panel b). To the extent that<br />

the collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> sectors raises the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> above the<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional rate, the share of these sectors <strong>in</strong> the population of<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners will rise. In Belgium, this is notably the case for the<br />

construction sector whose share <strong>in</strong>creases from 9 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts from 8 to<br />

17 percent (see Figure 5).<br />

To some extent, the wage distribution at the sector level of a Type II countries<br />

resembles the overall wage distribution of a Type I country. This can be seen<br />

<strong>in</strong> Figure 6 which shows the sectoral m<strong>in</strong>ima and wage distribution for the<br />

transport, storage and communication sector (panel a) and for real estate,<br />

rent<strong>in</strong>g and bus<strong>in</strong>ess activities (panel b). The th<strong>in</strong> vertical l<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong> these<br />

figures represent respectively the <strong>in</strong>terprofessional <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage (7.80<br />

euros) and the sectoral m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong> the two sectors. As can been seen, once we<br />

disaggregate the total population <strong>in</strong>to sectors of activity, a truncation of the<br />

wage distribution appears at the level of the sectoral <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage (see<br />

Figure 6).<br />

Report 124<br />

39


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

Figure 5 Distribution of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners accord<strong>in</strong>g to sector of activity <strong>in</strong><br />

Belgium — a) <strong>in</strong>ter-professional <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> (2007)<br />

n<br />

17%<br />

m<br />

12%<br />

n<br />

15%<br />

m<br />

11%<br />

Notes<br />

Sectors accord<strong>in</strong>g to NACE Rev. 1: a+b = Agriculture, hunt<strong>in</strong>g and forestry + Fish<strong>in</strong>g; c+d+e = M<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and quarry<strong>in</strong>g +<br />

Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g + Electricity, gas and water supply; f = Construction; g = <strong>Who</strong>lesale and retail trade; repair of motor<br />

vehicles, motorcycles and personal and household goods; h= Hotels and restaurants; i = Transport, storage and<br />

communication; j = F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediation; k = Real estate, rent<strong>in</strong>g and bus<strong>in</strong>ess activities; l = Public adm<strong>in</strong>istration<br />

and defence, compulsory social security ; m = Education; n = Health and social work; o+p+q = Other community,<br />

social and personal service activities + Private households with employed persons +Extra-territorial organizations and<br />

bodies.<br />

40 Report 124<br />

l<br />

5%<br />

o+p+q<br />

13%<br />

l<br />

6%<br />

o+p+q<br />

10%<br />

k<br />

8%<br />

a+b<br />

2%<br />

k<br />

6%<br />

j<br />

1%<br />

c+d+e<br />

10%<br />

j<br />

1%<br />

i<br />

6%<br />

i<br />

7%<br />

h<br />

6%<br />

f<br />

8%<br />

h<br />

5%<br />

g<br />

13%<br />

Figure 5 b) employment-weighted average sector m<strong>in</strong>ima (2007)<br />

a+b<br />

2%<br />

c+d+e<br />

9%<br />

f<br />

17%<br />

g<br />

10%


<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

Figure 6 Intra-sectoral wage distribution and <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> Belgium (2007)<br />

a) Transport, storage and communication<br />

0 5 10<br />

percent<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50<br />

gross hourly wage (euros)<br />

Source: BE-SILC; current 2007 euros; th<strong>in</strong> vertical l<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong>dicate levels of <strong>in</strong>terprofessional <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage (7.8 euros per<br />

hour) and employment-weighted average of sector <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> (9.18 euros per hour).<br />

Figure 6 b) real estate, rent<strong>in</strong>g and bus<strong>in</strong>ess activities<br />

0 2 4 6 8 10<br />

percent<br />

0 10 20 30 40<br />

gross hourly wage (euros)<br />

Source: BE-SILC; current 2007 euros; th<strong>in</strong> vertical l<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong>dicate levels of <strong>in</strong>terprofessional <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage (7.8 euros per<br />

hour) and employment-weighted average of sector <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> (10.21 euros per hour).<br />

Report 124<br />

41


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

3.2.4 Household characteristics of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, we have used the <strong>in</strong>formation on household characteristics <strong>in</strong> the EU-<br />

SILC to shed more light on the overall liv<strong>in</strong>g conditions of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

earners. We notably compared the latter to the rest of the population with<br />

respect to the average household size, the total disposable household <strong>in</strong>come,<br />

and the risk of poverty.<br />

The average figures for these three variables are shown <strong>in</strong> Table 6. All<br />

countries <strong>in</strong> our sample show a similar pattern <strong>in</strong> terms of household size: the<br />

population of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners consistently live <strong>in</strong> households that are<br />

on average larger compared to the population with higher <strong>wages</strong>.<br />

Unsurpris<strong>in</strong>gly, the average disposable household <strong>in</strong>come is also consistently<br />

lower <strong>in</strong> households with <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>in</strong> most of the<br />

countries <strong>in</strong> our sample, the risk of poverty of the household is on average<br />

considerably higher for the population of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners.<br />

Table 6 Household characteristics of employees below and above <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (2007)<br />

TYPE I COUNTRIES<br />

Bulgaria<br />

Hungary<br />

Ireland<br />

Poland<br />

Romania<br />

Spa<strong>in</strong><br />

United K<strong>in</strong>gdom<br />

TYPE II COUNTRIES<br />

Belgium<br />

Germany<br />

Household size<br />

(<strong>in</strong> persons)<br />

MW<br />

3.8<br />

(1.6)<br />

3.3<br />

(1.3)<br />

3.4<br />

(1.3)<br />

3.6<br />

(1.5)<br />

3.6<br />

(1.5)<br />

3.2<br />

(1.1)<br />

2.9<br />

(1.3)<br />

3.0<br />

(1.4)<br />

NA<br />

Household <strong>in</strong>come<br />

(2007 euros)<br />

MW<br />

3221.2<br />

(1931.3)<br />

5684.2<br />

(2639.4)<br />

32921.1<br />

(16020.4)<br />

6158.3<br />

(4233.6)<br />

3228.8<br />

(1996.7)<br />

18078<br />

(8947.9)<br />

32311.1<br />

(25534.0)<br />

24280.6<br />

(12713.8)<br />

NA<br />

Household at risk<br />

of poverty 2<br />

MW<br />

6.1<br />

(24.0)<br />

2.9<br />

(16.9)<br />

3.7<br />

(18.8)<br />

6.0<br />

(23.8)<br />

4.0<br />

(19.6)<br />

6.3<br />

(24.4)<br />

4.3<br />

(20.4)<br />

2.5<br />

(15.6)<br />

NA


3.3 Regression analysis<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

The preced<strong>in</strong>g section compared the population of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners to<br />

the rest of the labour force and found that the two groups differ on average<br />

with respect to <strong>in</strong>dividual, job, and household characteristics. In this section,<br />

we look at the issue from a different angle and ask what determ<strong>in</strong>es the<br />

likelihood of receiv<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage. This is done by estimat<strong>in</strong>g logistic<br />

regressions that predict the conditional probability of receiv<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage <strong>in</strong> each of the countries under consideration. One of the advantages of<br />

this procedure is that it allows to estimate the relationship between the<br />

aforementioned characteristics and the likelihood of be<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

earner under ceteris paribus conditions, i.e. by hold<strong>in</strong>g all other<br />

characteristics constant. This is particularly relevant for our question s<strong>in</strong>ce it<br />

allows to disentangle the effects of the different characteristics. For example,<br />

we have seen that <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> earners are on average younger and sign on more<br />

temporary contracts than the rest of the labour force. But is it the age or the<br />

contract type that is l<strong>in</strong>ked to the likelihood of receiv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>?<br />

And what is the size of these effects <strong>in</strong> each country ?<br />

The dependent variable <strong>in</strong> the estimated model is a dummy variable that<br />

takes the value of 1 if the <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>earns</strong> the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage that applies to<br />

her and 0 otherwise. This variable is then regressed on a set of 16 explanatory<br />

variables that capture the follow<strong>in</strong>g characteristics:<br />

— a dummy variable measur<strong>in</strong>g the existence of a temporary work contract<br />

(the reference modality are permanent work contracts)<br />

— a dummy variable for part-time employment, def<strong>in</strong>ed as less than 35<br />

weekly work hours (the reference modality is full-time employment with<br />

more or equal than 35 weekly work hours)<br />

— a dummy variable captur<strong>in</strong>g whether the <strong>in</strong>dividual switched jobs dur<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the past year (the reference modality is absence of job switches)<br />

— three dummy variables captur<strong>in</strong>g the length of labour market experience<br />

<strong>in</strong> number of years (the reference category is less than 5 years of labour<br />

market experience)<br />

— two dummy variables <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g the broad occupational categories "low<br />

white collar" and "blue collar" occupations that have been def<strong>in</strong>ed by<br />

regroup<strong>in</strong>g ISCO 88 two-digit occupational categories (the reference<br />

category are "high white collar" occupations). 11<br />

— six dummy variables <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>dividual's age (the reference<br />

category are workers aged between 35 and 45 years).<br />

— a sex dummy (the reference category is male)<br />

— two dummy variables for educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment based on ISCED levels<br />

(the reference category are ISCED levels 3 and 4)<br />

11. "High white-collar occupations" correspond to ISCO codes 11, 12, 13, 21, and 22. "Low whitecollar<br />

occupations" correspond to ISCO codes 23, 24, 31, 32, 33, and 34. "Blue-collar occupations"<br />

conta<strong>in</strong> codes 61, 71, 72, 73, 74, 81, 82, 83, 91, 92, 93, and 01.<br />

Report 124<br />

43


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

In order to control for employer characteristics, the model also <strong>in</strong>cludes three<br />

dummies for firm size (measured <strong>in</strong> terms of number of workers per<br />

establishment) and 11 dummies that control for the sector of activity of the<br />

employer.<br />

A logistic regression was estimated separately for each of the n<strong>in</strong>e countries<br />

<strong>in</strong> our sample. Table 7 reports the estimated coefficients for the seven<br />

countries with clean-cut <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems; Table 8 shows results for<br />

the two countries with complex systems. The reported significance levels are<br />

robust to heteroskedasticity. All models are statistically significant at the 1 per<br />

cent level and have a good fit, with pseudo-coefficients of determ<strong>in</strong>ation<br />

rang<strong>in</strong>g from 14 (Bulgaria) to 30 per cent (Germany).<br />

A positive coefficient <strong>in</strong> Tables 7 and 8 <strong>in</strong>dicates that the characteristic is<br />

associated with higher odds of receiv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> than the reference<br />

group. Take, for example, the coefficient associated with temporary work<br />

contacts. In the UK, this coefficient was estimated to be equal to 0.52. Given<br />

that we have estimated a logistic regression, this means that the odds of a<br />

temporary contract holder of receiv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> are around 68.4 per<br />

cent (0.684 = e 0.521 - 1) higher than the odds of a permanent contract holder.<br />

Conversely, a negative coefficient <strong>in</strong>dicates a lower probability compared to<br />

the reference category. For <strong>in</strong>stance, the coefficient for the highest level of<br />

atta<strong>in</strong>ed education (ISCED levels 5 and 6) <strong>in</strong> the UK is estimated to be -0.46.<br />

Given that the reference category is medium education (ISCED levels 3 and<br />

4), we can say that the odds of a highly educated <strong>in</strong>dividual of receiv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> are about 37.1 per cent smaller than the odds of an <strong>in</strong>dividual<br />

with medium education (0.371 = e -0.464 - 1).<br />

Estimation results<br />

The results of the regression analysis are broadly <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the conclusions<br />

drawn from the descriptive statistics <strong>in</strong> the previous section. For most of the<br />

n<strong>in</strong>e countries <strong>in</strong> our sample we observe that:<br />

— temporary contracts are associated with higher odds of receiv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> than permanent contracts (this is the case <strong>in</strong> Bulgaria,<br />

Hungary, Poland, Romania, Spa<strong>in</strong>, Belgium, and Germany)<br />

— a job change <strong>in</strong>creases the odds of receiv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (Bulgaria,<br />

Hungary, Poland, Romania, Spa<strong>in</strong>, and Belgium)<br />

— the longer the work experience on the labour market, the lower are the<br />

odds of receiv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (Ireland, Poland, Spa<strong>in</strong>, Germany, and<br />

Belgium)<br />

— females are more likely to receive <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> than males <strong>in</strong> all<br />

countries<br />

— relative to medium levels of educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment, low education is<br />

associated with a greater and high education with a smaller probability of<br />

receiv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> all countries (exceptions are Ireland and<br />

Belgium where the coefficient of high education is not significant)<br />

44 Report 124


<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

— high white-collar occupations are less likely to earn <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong><br />

than low white collar and blue collar occupations (the blue collar<br />

coefficient is significant <strong>in</strong> all countries)<br />

— the youngest group of workers has higher odds of receiv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> compared to middle-aged workers <strong>in</strong> Hungary, Ireland,<br />

Spa<strong>in</strong>, the UK, Belgium, and Germany. In addition, elderly workers<br />

are also more exposed to <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> the latter four countries.<br />

An exception is the effect of part-time work: part time is associated with a<br />

higher probability of receiv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> Ireland, the United<br />

K<strong>in</strong>gdom, and Germany; but the opposite effect is observed <strong>in</strong> Bulgaria,<br />

Hungary, Spa<strong>in</strong>, Poland, and Belgium (albeit with <strong>in</strong>significant coefficients<br />

for Bulgaria, Poland, and Belgium). This suggests that part-time work<br />

arrangements play a different role depend<strong>in</strong>g on the national context.<br />

By and large, the regression results <strong>in</strong>dicate that the sign of the relationships<br />

between <strong>in</strong>dividual and job characteristics is fairly similar <strong>in</strong> all countries <strong>in</strong><br />

our sample; except for part time work, it appears that the underly<strong>in</strong>g<br />

mechanisms work <strong>in</strong> the same direction irrespective of the national context.<br />

This be<strong>in</strong>g said, it should be noted that the size of the effects can differ<br />

substantially across countries. For <strong>in</strong>stance, the positive impact of temporary<br />

contracts on the probability of receiv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> is much higher <strong>in</strong><br />

the two countries with complex systems (Belgium and Germany) than <strong>in</strong> the<br />

rest of the sample. Also the effect of white- and blue-collar categories differs<br />

strongly <strong>in</strong> magnitude, with coefficients rang<strong>in</strong>g from 0.54 (Ireland) to 1.71<br />

(Romania). In other words, while our regressions suggest that the<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>ants of earn<strong>in</strong>g <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> are relatively homogeneous across<br />

<strong>Europe</strong>, we also observe much heterogeneity as to the relative importance of<br />

each determ<strong>in</strong>ant.<br />

The Belgium <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage system is special <strong>in</strong> that it conta<strong>in</strong>s both a<br />

b<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terprofessional <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage that is def<strong>in</strong>ed at the national level<br />

and sectoral m<strong>in</strong>ima established through decentralised collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Given that <strong>in</strong> practice most workers are covered by a sectoral rather than by<br />

the national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong>, we have def<strong>in</strong>ed Belgium as a complex system. The<br />

regression analysis <strong>in</strong> Table 8 shows why it is important to take the sectoral<br />

level <strong>in</strong>to account: if we use the <strong>in</strong>terprofessional <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage to def<strong>in</strong>e the<br />

dependent variable <strong>in</strong> our model (column 3), almost all coefficients are<br />

altered compared to the model us<strong>in</strong>g the sectoral <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> (the sign of<br />

effects rema<strong>in</strong>s unchanged). In addition, the coefficient of determ<strong>in</strong>ation of<br />

the sectoral model is 4 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts higher compared to the model us<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the <strong>in</strong>terprofessional <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong>, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that the former fits better to the<br />

variation <strong>in</strong> the data.<br />

Report 124<br />

45


Explanatory variables<br />

Temporary work contract<br />

Part time (< 35 hours)<br />

Job change dur<strong>in</strong>g last year<br />

Work experience 2 (years = [5;10[)<br />

Work experience 3 (years = [10;20[)<br />

Work experience 4 (years >=20)<br />

White collar II occupation1 Blue collar occupation 1<br />

Age category 1 (age = [15;25[)<br />

Age category 2 (age = [25;30[)<br />

Age category 3 (age = [30;35[)<br />

Age category 5 (age = [45;60[)<br />

Age category 6 (age >= 60)<br />

Female<br />

Low education (ISCED = [0;2])<br />

High education (ISCED = [5;6])<br />

Firm size 1 (< 5 workers)<br />

Firm size 2 (>= 5 and < 10 workers)<br />

Firm size 4 (>= 20 workers)<br />

NACE1 = A+B (Agriculture, hunt<strong>in</strong>g and<br />

forestry; Fish<strong>in</strong>g)<br />

NACE1 = F (Construction)<br />

NACE1 = G (<strong>Who</strong>lesale and retail trade)<br />

NACE1 = H (Hotels and restaurants)<br />

NACE1 = I (Transport, storage and<br />

communication)<br />

NACE1 = J (F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediation)<br />

NACE1 = K (Real estate, rent<strong>in</strong>g and<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess activities)<br />

NACE1 = L (Public adm<strong>in</strong>istration and<br />

defence, compulsory social security)<br />

NACE1 = M (Education)<br />

NACE1 = N (Health and social work)<br />

NACE1 = = O + P + Q (Other<br />

community, social and personal service<br />

activities; Private households; Extraterritorial<br />

organizations)<br />

Observations<br />

Pseudo-R-squared<br />

Model significance<br />

François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

Table 7 Coefficients from logistic regression — countries with clean-cut systems<br />

(dependent variable: <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>earns</strong> applicable <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage)<br />

46 Report 124<br />

Bulgaria<br />

0.74***<br />

-0.96<br />

1.03***<br />

-0.11<br />

-0.02<br />

-0.33<br />

0.48<br />

0.79**<br />

-0.55<br />

0.33<br />

-0.14<br />

0.04<br />

0.02<br />

0.50**<br />

0.57***<br />

-1.02**<br />

0.58*<br />

0.31<br />

-0.62***<br />

-0.18<br />

0.31<br />

0.10<br />

0.14<br />

-0.43<br />

-0.48<br />

0.52<br />

0.70**<br />

-1.09<br />

1.24***<br />

1.27***<br />

3517<br />

0.14<br />

0.00<br />

Hungary<br />

0.76***<br />

-0.42*<br />

0.58***<br />

n.a.<br />

n.a.<br />

n.a.<br />

0.90***<br />

1.43***<br />

0.95***<br />

0.29*<br />

0.43***<br />

0.09<br />

-0.17<br />

0.51***<br />

0.55***<br />

-1.41***<br />

0.67***<br />

0.13<br />

-0.43***<br />

0.80***<br />

0.62***<br />

0.48***<br />

0.62***<br />

0.00<br />

-1.24<br />

0.81***<br />

0.02<br />

-0.22<br />

-0.19<br />

0.23<br />

6313<br />

0.17<br />

0.00<br />

Ireland<br />

0.26<br />

0.37**<br />

-0.26<br />

-0.92***<br />

-1.25***<br />

-1.35***<br />

0.42*<br />

0.54**<br />

0.96**<br />

0.52<br />

0.01<br />

-0.10<br />

0.03<br />

0.53***<br />

0.46**<br />

-0.74***<br />

0.78***<br />

0.04<br />

-0.48**<br />

0.47<br />

-0.40<br />

0.07<br />

0.95***<br />

-0.23<br />

-2.43**<br />

-0.28<br />

-0.75**<br />

-0.37<br />

-0.62*<br />

0.31<br />

2964<br />

0.21<br />

0.00<br />

Poland<br />

0.76***<br />

-0.12<br />

0.58***<br />

-0.01<br />

-0.16<br />

-0.40*<br />

0.86***<br />

1.09***<br />

0.26<br />

0.04<br />

-0.24<br />

0.11<br />

0.36<br />

0.62***<br />

0.42***<br />

-0.81***<br />

-0.08<br />

0.09<br />

-0.58***<br />

0.71***<br />

0.23*<br />

0.60***<br />

0.84***<br />

0.21<br />

0.15<br />

0.63***<br />

0.21<br />

-0.39<br />

0.02<br />

0.22<br />

10184<br />

0.14<br />

0.00<br />

Romania<br />

0.71**<br />

0.04<br />

0.80***<br />

0.86**<br />

0.46<br />

0.03<br />

1.59***<br />

1.71***<br />

0.28<br />

0.14<br />

0.04<br />

-0.11<br />

0.15<br />

0.75***<br />

0.70***<br />

-0.78*<br />

0.91***<br />

0.53**<br />

-0.33**<br />

1.24***<br />

-0.01<br />

-0.04<br />

0.97***<br />

-0.47*<br />

-1.27<br />

0.25<br />

-0.10<br />

0.57*<br />

0.68**<br />

-0.77<br />

5052<br />

0.16<br />

0.00<br />

Spa<strong>in</strong><br />

0.63***<br />

-0.65***<br />

0.52***<br />

-0.96***<br />

-1.17***<br />

-1.29***<br />

0.39*<br />

0.73***<br />

0.58**<br />

0.30<br />

0.09<br />

0.11<br />

0.89***<br />

0.83***<br />

0.33**<br />

-0.08<br />

0.89***<br />

0.08<br />

0.06<br />

0.83***<br />

-0.36<br />

0.38*<br />

0.84***<br />

0.78***<br />

0.04<br />

0.31<br />

-0.21<br />

0.28<br />

0.19<br />

1.01***<br />

10505<br />

0.15<br />

0.00<br />

UK<br />

n.a.<br />

0.52***<br />

n.a.<br />

n.a.<br />

n.a.<br />

n.a.<br />

0.89***<br />

1.25***<br />

0.60***<br />

0.48**<br />

0.33*<br />

0.15<br />

0.67***<br />

0.53***<br />

0.44***<br />

-0.46***<br />

0.54***<br />

0.30*<br />

-0.22<br />

0.48<br />

-0.23<br />

0.68***<br />

0.99***<br />

-0.09<br />

-1.18***<br />

0.19<br />

-0.58**<br />

0.71***<br />

0.30<br />

0.67***<br />

Source: EU-SILC 2007; significance levels: * p


Explanatory variables<br />

Temporary work contract<br />

Part time (< 35 hours)<br />

Job change dur<strong>in</strong>g last year<br />

Work experience 2 (years = [5;10[)<br />

Work experience 3 (years = [10;20[)<br />

Work experience 4 (years >=20)<br />

White collar II occupation 1<br />

Blue collar occupation 1<br />

Age category 1 (age = [15;25[)<br />

Age category 2 (age = [25;30[)<br />

Age category 3 (age = [30;35[)<br />

Age category 5 (age = [45;60[)<br />

Age category 6 (age >= 60)<br />

Female<br />

Low education (ISCED = [0;2])<br />

High education (ISCED = [5;6])<br />

Firm size 1 (< 5 workers)<br />

Firm size 2 (>= 5 and < 10 workers)<br />

Firm size 4 (>= 20 workers)<br />

NACE1 = A+B (Agriculture, hunt<strong>in</strong>g and forestry; Fish<strong>in</strong>g)<br />

NACE1 = F (Construction)<br />

NACE1 = G (<strong>Who</strong>lesale and retail trade)<br />

NACE1 = H (Hotels and restaurants)<br />

NACE1 = I (Transport, storage and communication)<br />

NACE1 = J (F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediation)<br />

NACE1 = K (Real estate, rent<strong>in</strong>g and bus<strong>in</strong>ess activities)<br />

NACE1 = L (Public adm<strong>in</strong>istration and defence, compulsory social<br />

security)<br />

NACE1 = M (Education)<br />

NACE1 = N (Health and social work)<br />

NACE1 = = O + P + Q (Other community, social and personal service<br />

activities; Private households; Extra-territorial organizations)<br />

Observations<br />

Pseudo-R-squared<br />

Model significance<br />

Belgium<br />

(sector m<strong>in</strong>ima)<br />

0.95***<br />

-0.08<br />

0.90***<br />

-1.06***<br />

-1.40***<br />

-1.77***<br />

0.21<br />

0.78***<br />

0.36<br />

0.08<br />

0.17<br />

-0.01<br />

1.07***<br />

0.42***<br />

0.35**<br />

-0.16<br />

0.70***<br />

0.17<br />

-0.31*<br />

1.42***<br />

1.73***<br />

0.41*<br />

1.58***<br />

0.63**<br />

-0.74<br />

1.07***<br />

0.22<br />

0.86***<br />

0.81***<br />

0.87***<br />

4999<br />

0.19<br />

0.00<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

Table 8 Coefficients from logistic regression — countries with complex <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems<br />

(dependent variable: <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>earns</strong> applicable <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage)<br />

Belgium<br />

(<strong>in</strong>terprof. m<strong>in</strong>ima)<br />

1.08***<br />

-0.12<br />

0.81***<br />

-0.86***<br />

-1.07***<br />

-1.06***<br />

0.12<br />

0.62***<br />

0.64**<br />

0.42<br />

0.48**<br />

-0.15<br />

1.10***<br />

0.41***<br />

0.41**<br />

-0.09<br />

0.84***<br />

0.04<br />

-0.33*<br />

1.15**<br />

0.22<br />

0.40<br />

0.77**<br />

0.47<br />

-0.70<br />

0.40<br />

0.10<br />

0.48<br />

0.70***<br />

0.87***<br />

4999<br />

0.15<br />

0.00<br />

Germany<br />

(sector m<strong>in</strong>ima)<br />

1.42***<br />

0.91***<br />

n.a.<br />

-0.40***<br />

-0.78***<br />

-1.34***<br />

0.50***<br />

1.37***<br />

1.56***<br />

0.55***<br />

0.25*<br />

0.19**<br />

0.81***<br />

0.61***<br />

0.50***<br />

-0.56***<br />

0.73***<br />

0.12<br />

-0.63***<br />

0.26<br />

0.21<br />

0.22*<br />

-0.39*<br />

-0.44***<br />

0.74***<br />

-0.24*<br />

-1.02***<br />

-0.81***<br />

-1.51***<br />

-0.01<br />

Source: BE-SILC 2007 for Belgium, German Socio-economic Panel for Germany; significance levels: * p


4. Summary and suggestions<br />

for further research<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum <strong>wages</strong> cont<strong>in</strong>ue to stir controversial policy debates. The current<br />

economic climate <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> might contribute to <strong>in</strong>crease the pressure on<br />

<strong>wages</strong> at the bottom of the wage distribution and, as a consequence, renew the<br />

<strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> wage floors as a tool to protect workers and employees. This report<br />

contributes to a better understand<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> by provid<strong>in</strong>g a solid<br />

empirical assessment of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage policies and their socio-economic<br />

consequences for a range of <strong>Europe</strong>an countries.<br />

An obstacle to provid<strong>in</strong>g comparable <strong>in</strong>formation on wage m<strong>in</strong>ima for<br />

different countries is the <strong>in</strong>stitutional diversity of <strong>Europe</strong>an <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

systems. This diversity reflects the historical evolution of each of the national<br />

collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g systems. While one has to acknowledge the existence of<br />

national idiosyncrasies, it is nevertheless useful to dist<strong>in</strong>guish <strong>Europe</strong>an<br />

countries with the help of a straightforward typology. Central and Eastern<br />

<strong>Europe</strong>an countries, the UK and Ireland, as well as Luxembourg, the<br />

Netherlands, Cyprus, Spa<strong>in</strong>, and Portugal operate <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems<br />

that produce a "clean cut" <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>come distribution. By contrast, all of the<br />

Nordic countries, Austria, Belgium, Germany, Greece, and Italy operate<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems that are "complex", i.e. many different m<strong>in</strong>ima coexist<br />

side by side so that the left tail of the wage distribution is much smoother<br />

<strong>in</strong> these countries. This typology therefore helps to l<strong>in</strong>k the <strong>in</strong>stitutional<br />

arrangements that underlie the different <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage system and the<br />

overall shape of the <strong>in</strong>come distribution. The two types also differ with respect<br />

to who is affected by <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage policies: whereas <strong>in</strong> clean-cut systems<br />

the affected <strong>in</strong>dividuals are concentrated <strong>in</strong> a small segment of the wage<br />

distribution, wage floors <strong>in</strong> complex systems can also affect workers and<br />

employees with relatively high remunerations.<br />

In addition to qualitative differences between <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems, the<br />

report documents <strong>in</strong>ternational variations <strong>in</strong> the (absolute and relative) levels<br />

of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>. While these levels follow no clear geographical pattern, it<br />

appears that complex systems are more likely to generate relatively high wage<br />

floors compared to systems that determ<strong>in</strong>e a s<strong>in</strong>gle wage <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> at the<br />

national level. By and large, ‘clean-cut’ systems typically <strong>in</strong>volve social<br />

partners to a relatively low extent and offer them merely a consultative<br />

function <strong>in</strong> the process of sett<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage. As a consequence, these<br />

countries seem to be less effective <strong>in</strong> guarantee<strong>in</strong>g wage floors that help to<br />

compress the lower end of the wage distribution and protect wage earners<br />

from poverty.<br />

48 Report 124


<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

The comparison of the two countries with complex <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage systems,<br />

Belgium and Germany, suggests that a strong role of collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

does not <strong>in</strong> itself guarantee higher levels of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>. Indeed,<br />

Germany appears to be an important exception to the protective function of<br />

collectively barga<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>: we observe considerable differences<br />

<strong>in</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> between sectors and regions, as well as low barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

coverage <strong>in</strong> particular <strong>in</strong> those sectors and regions where <strong>wages</strong> floors tend to<br />

be relatively low. We conclude that collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g has to be embedded<br />

<strong>in</strong> other <strong>in</strong>stitutional features (e.g. effective erga omnes procedures, high<br />

union and employer densities, high collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g autonomy) <strong>in</strong> order<br />

to generate <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> with a strong ‘bite’.<br />

An important contribution of the report is to provide a statistical panorama of<br />

the population of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners. Compared to the rest of the<br />

population, the empirical results show that this group is characterised by a<br />

lower average age; on average more female employment; lower levels of<br />

educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment than workers with higher <strong>wages</strong>; a considerably<br />

higher share of employees with temporary work contracts; and a higher share<br />

of part time employment than the sub-population with higher <strong>wages</strong>. Even<br />

more important <strong>in</strong> terms of the affected <strong>in</strong>dividuals' well be<strong>in</strong>g is the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g<br />

that <strong>in</strong> all countries <strong>in</strong> the sample <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners live <strong>in</strong> bigger<br />

households that dispose of significantly lower <strong>in</strong>come and that are at a higher<br />

risk of liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> poverty.<br />

These relationships between <strong>in</strong>dividual characteristics and <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong><br />

stand up to the regression analysis we carried out. A logistic regression<br />

modell<strong>in</strong>g the likelihood of receiv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> each of the n<strong>in</strong>e<br />

countries <strong>in</strong> our sample suggests that the underly<strong>in</strong>g effects work <strong>in</strong> the same<br />

direction across <strong>Europe</strong>. In other words, the relationships between <strong>in</strong>dividual<br />

and job characteristics and the likelihood of receiv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> have<br />

the same signs <strong>in</strong> most countries (the effect of part time be<strong>in</strong>g the only<br />

exception to this rule). While this led us to conclude that the determ<strong>in</strong>ants of<br />

be<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earner are relatively similar across <strong>Europe</strong>, we also<br />

noted that the magnitude of the different effects is rather heterogeneous.<br />

There are several l<strong>in</strong>es of <strong>in</strong>vestigation <strong>in</strong> which our results could be extended.<br />

We f<strong>in</strong>ish by briefly mention<strong>in</strong>g the most relevant suggestions for further<br />

comparative research on <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong>.<br />

A first l<strong>in</strong>e of <strong>in</strong>vestigation could take <strong>in</strong>to account that the composition of the<br />

population affected by the Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex might differ across countries; it would<br />

therefore be advisable to compare Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices for groups with similar<br />

characteristics (such as age, gender, occupation, educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment,<br />

contract type etc.). Our report documents that the effect of these categories<br />

differs <strong>in</strong> magnitude (albeit not <strong>in</strong> sign) across <strong>Europe</strong>; a differentiation of<br />

Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dices might be able to account for some of this cross-country<br />

variation.<br />

Report 124<br />

49


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

Second, it would be useful to compare the empirical results presented <strong>in</strong> this<br />

report with the national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage data that is published by other<br />

sources such as the OECD database, both <strong>in</strong> terms of the absolute and relative<br />

level of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> and the correspond<strong>in</strong>g employment spikes. Given<br />

that standard analyses typically fail to account for the <strong>in</strong>fra-national<br />

differentiation of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage rates, it is notably <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g to what extent<br />

our employment-weighted figures differ from sources that do not apply this<br />

correction. In addition, a comparison with other sources would also allow to<br />

p<strong>in</strong>po<strong>in</strong>t which knowledge gaps have been filled by our research, <strong>in</strong> particular<br />

as regards Type II countries that are typically not <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational<br />

comparisons.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, this report was restricted to n<strong>in</strong>e countries and it would certa<strong>in</strong>ly be<br />

useful to extent the analysis to other countries. For <strong>in</strong>stance, important cases<br />

that could be <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> further research along the l<strong>in</strong>es presented here are<br />

France, the Netherlands, or Italy. Given the complexity of the German case, it<br />

would also be useful to comb<strong>in</strong>e the <strong>in</strong>formation presented above with more<br />

accurate data on collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g coverage at the sector level.<br />

50 Report 124


Statistical appendix<br />

A. Wage distribution and m<strong>in</strong>ima per country<br />

Figure A.1 Wage distribution and m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong> Ireland (2007)<br />

0 5 10 15<br />

percent<br />

Ireland (2007)<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

0 20 40 60 80<br />

gross hourly wage (euros)<br />

Source: IE-SILC; current 2007 euros; th<strong>in</strong> vertical l<strong>in</strong>es represent levels of national m<strong>in</strong>ima (differentiated by age,<br />

educational activity, and job tenure).<br />

Figure A.2 Wage distribution and m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong> Poland (2007)<br />

0 5 10<br />

percent<br />

Poland (2007)<br />

0 5 10 15<br />

gross hourly wage (euros)<br />

Source: PL-SILC; current 2007 euros; th<strong>in</strong> vertical l<strong>in</strong>es represent levels of national m<strong>in</strong>ima (differentiated by labour<br />

market experience)<br />

Report 124<br />

51


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

Figure A.3 Wage distribution and m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong> Romania (2007)<br />

0 2 4 6 8 10<br />

percent<br />

0 2 4 6<br />

gross hourly wage (euros)<br />

52 Report 124<br />

Romania (2007)<br />

Source: RO-SILC; current 2007 euros; th<strong>in</strong> vertical l<strong>in</strong>es represents level of national <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage.<br />

Figure A.4 Wage distribution and m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong> Spa<strong>in</strong> (2007)<br />

0 2 4 6 8 10<br />

percent<br />

Spa<strong>in</strong> (2007)<br />

0 10 20 30<br />

gross hourly wage (euros)<br />

Source: ES-SILC; current 2007 euros; th<strong>in</strong> vertical l<strong>in</strong>es represent levels of national m<strong>in</strong>ima (differentiated by disability<br />

status, educational activity, and job tenure).


<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

Figure A.5 Wage distribution and m<strong>in</strong>ima <strong>in</strong> the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom (2007)<br />

0 5 10 15<br />

percent<br />

United K<strong>in</strong>gdom (2007)<br />

0 20 40 60 80 100<br />

gross hourly wage (euros)<br />

Source : UK-SILC; current 2007 euros; th<strong>in</strong> vertical l<strong>in</strong>es represent levels of national m<strong>in</strong>ima (differentiated by age).<br />

Report 124<br />

53


B. Levels of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> and share of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage earners by sector and country<br />

Table B.1 Belgium<br />

Proportion of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> earners <strong>in</strong> sector Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

scenario MW<br />

= 0.5*median<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

Employmentweighted<br />

average<br />

of sector m<strong>in</strong>ima<br />

Maximum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

Percent<br />

Obs.<br />

Label NACE Rev.1 : To use<br />

until the 2008 operation<br />

<strong>in</strong>cluded<br />

NACE1<br />

François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

0.76<br />

0.67<br />

0.20<br />

0.30<br />

0.20<br />

9.17<br />

9.41<br />

7.92<br />

0.6<br />

32<br />

Agriculture, hunt<strong>in</strong>g and forestry +<br />

Fish<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a+b<br />

0.55<br />

0.48<br />

0.04<br />

0.06<br />

0.04<br />

9.13<br />

11.73<br />

7.94<br />

18.2<br />

930<br />

M<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and quarry<strong>in</strong>g +<br />

Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g + Electricity, gas<br />

and water supply<br />

c+d+e<br />

54 Report 124<br />

0.84<br />

0.63<br />

0.58<br />

0.59<br />

0.09<br />

0.10<br />

0.33<br />

0.13<br />

0.09<br />

0.10<br />

11.60<br />

8.58<br />

11.61<br />

13.21<br />

10.54<br />

7.80<br />

5.9<br />

9.2<br />

299<br />

471<br />

Construction<br />

<strong>Who</strong>lesale and retail trade; repair<br />

of motor vehicles, motorcycles and<br />

personal and household goods<br />

f<br />

g<br />

0.84<br />

0.60<br />

0.71<br />

0.52<br />

0.14<br />

0.06<br />

0.39<br />

0.09<br />

0.21<br />

0.07<br />

9.45<br />

9.18<br />

9.45<br />

9.18<br />

9.45<br />

8.74<br />

1.8<br />

7.0<br />

90<br />

358<br />

Hotels and restaurants<br />

Transport, storage and<br />

communication<br />

h<br />

i<br />

0.40<br />

0.66<br />

0.38<br />

0.52<br />

0.01<br />

0.06<br />

0.02<br />

0.13<br />

0.01<br />

0.06<br />

8.46<br />

8.46<br />

10.21<br />

10.64<br />

8.46<br />

7.80<br />

4.9<br />

7.3<br />

250<br />

374<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediation<br />

Real estate, rent<strong>in</strong>g and bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

activities<br />

j<br />

k<br />

0.56<br />

0.49<br />

0.03<br />

0.05<br />

0.03<br />

9.18<br />

9.18<br />

9.18<br />

12.4<br />

633<br />

Public adm<strong>in</strong>istration and defence,<br />

compulsory social security<br />

l<br />

0.53<br />

0.58<br />

0.46<br />

0.53<br />

0.07<br />

0.07<br />

0.11<br />

0.11<br />

0.07<br />

0.08<br />

9.10<br />

8.84<br />

9.10<br />

9.10<br />

9.09<br />

8.00<br />

11.9<br />

15.0<br />

605<br />

765<br />

0.68<br />

0.62<br />

0.15<br />

0.19<br />

0.16<br />

8.75<br />

9.17<br />

7.80<br />

5.8<br />

293<br />

Education<br />

Health and social work<br />

Other community, social and<br />

personal service activities + Private<br />

households with employed persons<br />

+Extra-territorial organizations and<br />

bodies<br />

m<br />

n<br />

o+p+q<br />

0.60<br />

0.52<br />

0.07<br />

0.11<br />

0.07<br />

9.22<br />

13.21<br />

7.80<br />

100<br />

5100<br />

—<br />

All<br />

sectors


Table B.2 Bulgaria<br />

Proportion of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> earners <strong>in</strong> sector Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

scenario MW<br />

= 0.5*median<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

Employmentweighted<br />

average<br />

of sector m<strong>in</strong>ima<br />

Maximum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

Percent<br />

Obs.<br />

Label NACE Rev.1 : To use<br />

until the 2008 operation<br />

<strong>in</strong>cluded<br />

NACE1<br />

—<br />

0.54<br />

0.28<br />

—<br />

0.12<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.48<br />

5.98<br />

264<br />

Agriculture, hunt<strong>in</strong>g and forestry +<br />

Fish<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a+b<br />

—<br />

0.38<br />

0.10<br />

—<br />

0.05<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.48<br />

38.77<br />

1543<br />

M<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and quarry<strong>in</strong>g +<br />

Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g + Electricity, gas<br />

and water supply<br />

c+d+e<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.36<br />

0.45<br />

0.04<br />

0.15<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.04<br />

0.07<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.48<br />

0.48<br />

1.7<br />

73<br />

13.95<br />

517<br />

Construction<br />

<strong>Who</strong>lesale and retail trade; repair<br />

of motor vehicles, motorcycles and<br />

personal and household goods<br />

f<br />

g<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.45<br />

0.36<br />

0.18<br />

0.05<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.08<br />

0.02<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.48<br />

0.48<br />

5.71<br />

7.37<br />

201<br />

283<br />

Hotels and restaurants<br />

Transport, storage and<br />

communication<br />

h<br />

i<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.27<br />

0.40<br />

0.02<br />

0.12<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.01<br />

0.05<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.48<br />

0.48<br />

2.07<br />

4.29<br />

71<br />

164<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediation<br />

Real estate, rent<strong>in</strong>g and bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

activities<br />

j<br />

k<br />

—<br />

0.36<br />

0.07<br />

—<br />

0.04<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.48<br />

7.99<br />

293<br />

l<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

Public adm<strong>in</strong>istration and defence,<br />

compulsory social security<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.42<br />

0.55<br />

0.06<br />

0.20<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.01<br />

0.12<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.48<br />

0.48<br />

5.45<br />

4.61<br />

233<br />

185<br />

—<br />

0.45<br />

0.24<br />

—<br />

0.12<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.48<br />

2.10<br />

77<br />

Education<br />

Health and social work<br />

Other community, social and<br />

personal service activities + Private<br />

households with employed persons<br />

+Extra-territorial organizations and<br />

bodies<br />

m<br />

n<br />

o+p+q<br />

Report 124<br />

—<br />

0.41<br />

0.12<br />

—<br />

0.06<br />

0.53<br />

0.53<br />

0.48<br />

100<br />

3904<br />

—<br />

All<br />

sectors<br />

55


Table B.3 Germany<br />

Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex<br />

Proportion of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> earners <strong>in</strong> sector<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

scenario<br />

MW =<br />

0.5*median<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

Employment-weighted<br />

average of sector<br />

m<strong>in</strong>ima<br />

Maximum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

Percent<br />

Obs.<br />

Label NACE Rev.1 : To use<br />

until the 2008 operation<br />

<strong>in</strong>cluded<br />

NACE1<br />

François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

0.76<br />

—<br />

0.21<br />

0.24<br />

—<br />

Total<br />

6.86<br />

East<br />

6.65<br />

West<br />

7.00<br />

8.43<br />

4.87<br />

0.94<br />

108<br />

Agriculture, hunt<strong>in</strong>g and forestry +<br />

Fish<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a+b<br />

0.59<br />

—<br />

0.11<br />

0.19<br />

—<br />

8.53<br />

8.46<br />

8.53<br />

11.80<br />

6.67<br />

24.85<br />

2125<br />

M<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and quarry<strong>in</strong>g +<br />

Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g + Electricity, gas<br />

and water supply<br />

c+d+e<br />

56 Report 124<br />

0.78<br />

0.77<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.10<br />

0.21<br />

0.23<br />

0.30<br />

—<br />

—<br />

9.42<br />

7.62<br />

8.61<br />

7.41<br />

9.65<br />

7.65<br />

10.00<br />

9.15<br />

5.26<br />

7.08<br />

5.56<br />

454<br />

13.62<br />

1099<br />

Construction<br />

<strong>Who</strong>lesale and retail trade; repair<br />

of motor vehicles, motorcycles and<br />

personal and household goods<br />

f<br />

g<br />

0.69<br />

0.45<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.39<br />

0.26<br />

0.15<br />

—<br />

—<br />

5.26<br />

6.71<br />

4.81<br />

5.71<br />

5.34<br />

7.13<br />

9.15<br />

8.40<br />

4.81<br />

3.91<br />

3.04<br />

5.47<br />

221<br />

469<br />

Hotels and restaurants<br />

Transport, storage and<br />

communication<br />

h<br />

i<br />

0.12<br />

0.10<br />

0.68<br />

0.51<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.20<br />

0.23<br />

12.21<br />

7.87<br />

10.97<br />

6.36<br />

3.92<br />

0.18<br />

—<br />

—<br />

11.35<br />

7.54<br />

11.23<br />

6.36<br />

11.36<br />

7.87<br />

10.16<br />

366<br />

888<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediation<br />

Real estate, rent<strong>in</strong>g and bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

activities<br />

j<br />

k<br />

0.52<br />

—<br />

0.03<br />

0.05<br />

—<br />

7.54<br />

7.20<br />

7.61<br />

7.61<br />

7.2<br />

7.25<br />

697<br />

Public adm<strong>in</strong>istration and defence,<br />

compulsory social security<br />

l<br />

0.47<br />

0.36<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.10<br />

0.15<br />

0.12<br />

0.09<br />

—<br />

—<br />

7.54<br />

5.28<br />

7.20<br />

4.33<br />

7.61<br />

5.45<br />

7.61<br />

5.45<br />

7.2<br />

6.65<br />

755<br />

0.66<br />

—<br />

0.23<br />

0.27<br />

—<br />

7.29<br />

7.08<br />

7.31<br />

9.02<br />

4.33<br />

6.22<br />

12.47<br />

6.04<br />

1114<br />

537<br />

Education<br />

Health and social work<br />

Other community, social and<br />

personal service activities + Private<br />

households with employed persons<br />

+Extra-territorial organizations and<br />

bodies<br />

m<br />

n<br />

o+p+q<br />

0.58<br />

—<br />

0.14<br />

0.19<br />

—<br />

7.63<br />

7.04<br />

7.76<br />

12.21<br />

3.91<br />

99.97<br />

8833<br />

—<br />

All<br />

sectors


Table B.4 Spa<strong>in</strong><br />

Proportion of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> earners <strong>in</strong> sector Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

scenario MW<br />

= 0.5*median<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

Employmentweighted<br />

average<br />

of sector m<strong>in</strong>ima<br />

Maximum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

Percent<br />

Obs.<br />

Label NACE Rev.1 : To use<br />

until the 2008 operation<br />

<strong>in</strong>cluded<br />

NACE1<br />

—<br />

0.57<br />

0.21<br />

—<br />

0.09<br />

3.44<br />

3.46<br />

2.42<br />

2.60<br />

307<br />

Agriculture, hunt<strong>in</strong>g and forestry +<br />

Fish<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a+b<br />

—<br />

0.39<br />

0.06<br />

—<br />

0.03<br />

3.43<br />

3.46<br />

2.42<br />

18.37<br />

2107<br />

M<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and quarry<strong>in</strong>g +<br />

Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g + Electricity, gas<br />

and water supply<br />

c+d+e<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.43<br />

0.48<br />

0.04<br />

0.10<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.02<br />

0.04<br />

3.43<br />

3.41<br />

3.46<br />

3.46<br />

2.42<br />

2.42<br />

10.84<br />

12.91<br />

1216<br />

1394<br />

Construction<br />

<strong>Who</strong>lesale and retail trade; repair<br />

of motor vehicles, motorcycles and<br />

personal and household goods<br />

f<br />

g<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.52<br />

0.39<br />

0.16<br />

0.06<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.09<br />

0.04<br />

3.41<br />

3.43<br />

3.46<br />

3.46<br />

2.42<br />

2.42<br />

5.55<br />

5.64<br />

665<br />

628<br />

Hotels and restaurants<br />

Transport, storage and<br />

communication<br />

h<br />

i<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.25<br />

0.41<br />

0.04<br />

0.07<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.02<br />

0.03<br />

3.37<br />

3.39<br />

3.46<br />

3.46<br />

2.42<br />

2.42<br />

3.54<br />

8.01<br />

346<br />

801<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediation<br />

Real estate, rent<strong>in</strong>g and bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

activities<br />

j<br />

k<br />

—<br />

0.29<br />

0.04<br />

—<br />

0.02<br />

3.39<br />

3.46<br />

2.42<br />

10.07<br />

1284<br />

l<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

Public adm<strong>in</strong>istration and defence,<br />

compulsory social security<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.23<br />

0.33<br />

0.04<br />

0.04<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.03<br />

0.02<br />

3.37<br />

3.40<br />

3.46<br />

3.46<br />

2.42<br />

2.42<br />

7.74<br />

7.33<br />

897<br />

874<br />

—<br />

0.52<br />

0.20<br />

—<br />

0.10<br />

3.41<br />

3.46<br />

2.42<br />

7.41<br />

808<br />

Education<br />

Health and social work<br />

Other community, social and<br />

personal service activities + Private<br />

households with employed persons<br />

+Extra-territorial organizations and<br />

bodies<br />

m<br />

n<br />

o+p+q<br />

Report 124<br />

—<br />

0.40<br />

0.08<br />

—<br />

0.04<br />

3.41<br />

3.46<br />

2.42<br />

100<br />

11327<br />

—<br />

All<br />

sectors<br />

57


Table B.5 Hungary<br />

Proportion of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> earners <strong>in</strong> sector Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

scenario MW<br />

= 0.5*median<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

Employmentweighted<br />

average<br />

of sector m<strong>in</strong>ima<br />

Maximum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

Percent<br />

Obs.<br />

Label NACE Rev.1 : To use<br />

until the 2008 operation<br />

<strong>in</strong>cluded<br />

NACE1<br />

François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

—<br />

0.79<br />

0.17<br />

—<br />

0.32<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

3.5<br />

244<br />

Agriculture, hunt<strong>in</strong>g and forestry +<br />

Fish<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a+b<br />

—<br />

0.59<br />

0.03<br />

—<br />

0.09<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

26.74<br />

1744<br />

M<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and quarry<strong>in</strong>g +<br />

Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g + Electricity, gas<br />

and water supply<br />

c+d+e<br />

58 Report 124<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.73<br />

0.66<br />

0.14<br />

0.06<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.25<br />

0.14<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

8.36<br />

13.79<br />

534<br />

859<br />

Construction<br />

<strong>Who</strong>lesale and retail trade; repair<br />

of motor vehicles, motorcycles and<br />

personal and household goods<br />

f<br />

g<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.73<br />

0.52<br />

0.07<br />

0.03<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.20<br />

0.09<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

3.74<br />

7.82<br />

218<br />

499<br />

Hotels and restaurants<br />

Transport, storage and<br />

communication<br />

h<br />

i<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.39<br />

0.50<br />

0.00<br />

0.05<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.01<br />

0.13<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

2.58<br />

6.31<br />

159<br />

390<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediation<br />

Real estate, rent<strong>in</strong>g and bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

activities<br />

j<br />

k<br />

—<br />

0.39<br />

0.02<br />

—<br />

0.06<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

8.3<br />

555<br />

Public adm<strong>in</strong>istration and defence,<br />

compulsory social security<br />

l<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.41<br />

0.54<br />

0.01<br />

0.01<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.03<br />

0.05<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

8.58<br />

6.91<br />

600<br />

496<br />

—<br />

0.54<br />

0.05<br />

—<br />

0.12<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

3.36<br />

215<br />

Education<br />

Health and social work<br />

Other community, social and<br />

personal service activities + Private<br />

households with employed persons<br />

+Extra-territorial organizations and<br />

bodies<br />

m<br />

n<br />

o+p+q<br />

—<br />

0.57<br />

0.05<br />

—<br />

0.12<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

1.51<br />

100<br />

6513<br />

—<br />

All<br />

sectors


Table B.6 Ireland<br />

Proportion of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> earners <strong>in</strong> sector Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

scenario MW<br />

= 0.5*median<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

Employmentweighted<br />

average<br />

of sector m<strong>in</strong>ima<br />

Maximum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

Percent<br />

Obs.<br />

Label NACE Rev.1 : To use<br />

until the 2008 operation<br />

<strong>in</strong>cluded<br />

NACE1<br />

—<br />

0.81<br />

0.28<br />

—<br />

0.30<br />

8.43<br />

8.48<br />

5.93<br />

0.83<br />

35<br />

Agriculture, hunt<strong>in</strong>g and forestry +<br />

Fish<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a+b<br />

—<br />

0.48<br />

0.06<br />

—<br />

0.07<br />

8.41<br />

8.48<br />

5.93<br />

11.04<br />

385<br />

M<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and quarry<strong>in</strong>g +<br />

Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g + Electricity, gas<br />

and water supply<br />

c+d+e<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.53<br />

0.68<br />

0.12<br />

0.14<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.10<br />

0.14<br />

8.39<br />

8.33<br />

8.48<br />

8.48<br />

5.93<br />

5.93<br />

8.58<br />

15.94<br />

255<br />

504<br />

Construction<br />

<strong>Who</strong>lesale and retail trade; repair<br />

of motor vehicles, motorcycles and<br />

personal and household goods<br />

f<br />

g<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.79<br />

0.52<br />

0.21<br />

0.04<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.23<br />

0.06<br />

8.29<br />

8.44<br />

8.48<br />

8.48<br />

5.93<br />

5.93<br />

6.66<br />

4.54<br />

206<br />

175<br />

Hotels and restaurants<br />

Transport, storage and<br />

communication<br />

h<br />

i<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.34<br />

0.57<br />

0.01<br />

0.07<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.01<br />

0.07<br />

8.33<br />

8.35<br />

8.48<br />

8.48<br />

5.93<br />

5.93<br />

5.83<br />

10.24<br />

194<br />

308<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediation<br />

Real estate, rent<strong>in</strong>g and bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

activities<br />

j<br />

k<br />

—<br />

0.39<br />

0.02<br />

—<br />

0.02<br />

8.44<br />

8.48<br />

5.93<br />

12.26<br />

434<br />

l<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

Public adm<strong>in</strong>istration and defence,<br />

compulsory social security<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.35<br />

0.51<br />

0.05<br />

0.07<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.06<br />

0.08<br />

8.43<br />

8.39<br />

8.48<br />

8.48<br />

5.93<br />

5.93<br />

7.40<br />

262<br />

431<br />

—<br />

0.63<br />

0.23<br />

—<br />

0.23<br />

8.27<br />

8.48<br />

5.93<br />

11.80<br />

4.89<br />

172<br />

Education<br />

Health and social work<br />

Other community, social and<br />

personal service activities + Private<br />

households with employed persons<br />

+Extra-territorial organizations and<br />

bodies<br />

m<br />

n<br />

o+p+q<br />

Report 124<br />

—<br />

0.53<br />

0.09<br />

—<br />

0.09<br />

8.37<br />

8.48<br />

5.93<br />

100<br />

3361<br />

—<br />

All<br />

sectors<br />

59


Table B.7 Poland<br />

Proportion of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> earners <strong>in</strong> sector Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

scenario MW<br />

= 0.5*median<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

Employmentweighted<br />

average<br />

of sector m<strong>in</strong>ima<br />

Maximum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

Percent<br />

Obs.<br />

Label NACE Rev.1 : To use<br />

until the 2008 operation<br />

<strong>in</strong>cluded<br />

NACE1<br />

François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

—<br />

0.65<br />

0.22<br />

—<br />

0.19<br />

1.42<br />

1.43<br />

1.14<br />

1.93<br />

247<br />

Agriculture, hunt<strong>in</strong>g and forestry +<br />

Fish<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a+b<br />

—<br />

0.48<br />

0.09<br />

—<br />

0.08<br />

1.42<br />

1.43<br />

1.14<br />

29.14<br />

3097<br />

M<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and quarry<strong>in</strong>g +<br />

Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g + Electricity, gas<br />

and water supply<br />

c+d+e<br />

60 Report 124<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.52<br />

0.61<br />

0.13<br />

0.18<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.11<br />

0.15<br />

1.42<br />

1.41<br />

1.43<br />

1.43<br />

1.14<br />

1.14<br />

9.17<br />

996<br />

53.65<br />

1369<br />

Construction<br />

<strong>Who</strong>lesale and retail trade; repair<br />

of motor vehicles, motorcycles and<br />

personal and household goods<br />

f<br />

g<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.70<br />

0.44<br />

0.28<br />

0.09<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.27<br />

0.08<br />

1.41<br />

1.42<br />

1.43<br />

1.43<br />

1.14<br />

1.14<br />

2.13<br />

7.53<br />

224<br />

773<br />

Hotels and restaurants<br />

Transport, storage and<br />

communication<br />

h<br />

i<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.31<br />

0.50<br />

0.06<br />

0.11<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.05<br />

0.10<br />

1.42<br />

1.42<br />

1.43<br />

1.43<br />

1.14<br />

1.14<br />

2.79<br />

6.29<br />

256<br />

596<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediation<br />

Real estate, rent<strong>in</strong>g and bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

activities<br />

j<br />

k<br />

—<br />

0.35<br />

0.05<br />

—<br />

0.05<br />

1.42<br />

1.43<br />

1.14<br />

7.85<br />

821<br />

Public adm<strong>in</strong>istration and defence,<br />

compulsory social security<br />

l<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.30<br />

0.46<br />

0.03<br />

0.05<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.03<br />

0.04<br />

1.42<br />

1.42<br />

1.43<br />

1.43<br />

1.14<br />

1.14<br />

9.51<br />

6.50<br />

996<br />

704<br />

—<br />

0.50<br />

0.15<br />

—<br />

0.12<br />

1.42<br />

1.43<br />

1.14<br />

3.75<br />

373<br />

Education<br />

Health and social work<br />

Other community, social and<br />

personal service activities + Private<br />

households with employed persons<br />

+Extra-territorial organizations and<br />

bodies<br />

m<br />

n<br />

o+p+q<br />

—<br />

0.48<br />

0.10<br />

—<br />

0.09<br />

1.42<br />

1.43<br />

1.14<br />

100<br />

10452<br />

—<br />

All<br />

sectors


Table B.8 Romania<br />

Proportion of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> earners <strong>in</strong> sector Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

scenario MW<br />

= 0.5*median<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

Employmentweighted<br />

average<br />

of sector m<strong>in</strong>ima<br />

Maximum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

Percent<br />

Obs.<br />

Label NACE Rev.1 : To use<br />

until the 2008 operation<br />

<strong>in</strong>cluded<br />

NACE1<br />

—<br />

0.60<br />

0.23<br />

—<br />

0.14<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

2.02<br />

114<br />

Agriculture, hunt<strong>in</strong>g and forestry +<br />

Fish<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a+b<br />

—<br />

0.47<br />

0.08<br />

—<br />

0.04<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

30.21<br />

1615<br />

M<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and quarry<strong>in</strong>g +<br />

Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g + Electricity, gas<br />

and water supply<br />

c+d+e<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.43<br />

0.47<br />

0.06<br />

0.10<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.03<br />

0.05<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

8.32<br />

17.64<br />

385<br />

836<br />

Construction<br />

<strong>Who</strong>lesale and retail trade; repair<br />

of motor vehicles, motorcycles and<br />

personal and household goods<br />

f<br />

g<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.64<br />

0.43<br />

0.22<br />

0.06<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.18<br />

0.03<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

2.46<br />

11.78<br />

118<br />

576<br />

Hotels and restaurants<br />

Transport, storage and<br />

communication<br />

h<br />

i<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.29<br />

0.39<br />

0.02<br />

0.07<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.01<br />

0.03<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

2.21<br />

5.09<br />

112<br />

255<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediation<br />

Real estate, rent<strong>in</strong>g and bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

activities<br />

j<br />

k<br />

—<br />

0.30<br />

0.06<br />

—<br />

0.02<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

4.83<br />

249<br />

l<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

Public adm<strong>in</strong>istration and defence,<br />

compulsory social security<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.37<br />

0.40<br />

0.08<br />

0.09<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.05<br />

0.07<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

5.90<br />

5.92<br />

317<br />

297<br />

—<br />

0.47<br />

0.08<br />

—<br />

0.03<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

3.63<br />

181<br />

Education<br />

Health and social work<br />

Other community, social and<br />

personal service activities + Private<br />

households with employed persons<br />

+Extra-territorial organizations and<br />

bodies<br />

m<br />

n<br />

o+p+q<br />

Report 124<br />

—<br />

0.44<br />

0.08<br />

—<br />

0.05<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

0.69<br />

100<br />

5055<br />

—<br />

All<br />

sectors<br />

61


Table B.9 United K<strong>in</strong>gdom<br />

Proportion of <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> earners <strong>in</strong> sector Kaitz <strong>in</strong>dex<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

scenario MW<br />

= 0.5*median<br />

sector<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong><br />

wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>terprofessional<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> wage<br />

Employmentweighted<br />

average<br />

of sector m<strong>in</strong>ima<br />

Maximum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum<br />

<strong>in</strong> sector<br />

Percent<br />

Obs.<br />

Label NACE Rev.1 : To use<br />

until the 2008 operation<br />

<strong>in</strong>cluded<br />

NACE1<br />

François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

—<br />

0.70<br />

0.26<br />

—<br />

0.21<br />

7.63<br />

7.86<br />

4.85<br />

0.87<br />

60<br />

Agriculture, hunt<strong>in</strong>g and forestry +<br />

Fish<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a+b<br />

—<br />

0.49<br />

0.05<br />

—<br />

0.06<br />

7.82<br />

7.86<br />

4.85<br />

15.40<br />

1094<br />

M<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and quarry<strong>in</strong>g +<br />

Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g + Electricity, gas<br />

and water supply<br />

c+d+e<br />

62 Report 124<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.50<br />

0.68<br />

0.05<br />

0.12<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.05<br />

0.16<br />

7.77<br />

7.67<br />

7.86<br />

7.86<br />

4.85<br />

4.85<br />

5.82<br />

14.37<br />

402<br />

963<br />

Construction<br />

<strong>Who</strong>lesale and retail trade; repair<br />

of motor vehicles, motorcycles and<br />

personal and household goods<br />

f<br />

g<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.78<br />

0.54<br />

0.26<br />

0.04<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.28<br />

0.06<br />

7.53<br />

7.83<br />

7.86<br />

7.86<br />

4.85<br />

4.85<br />

3.23<br />

6.11<br />

204<br />

420<br />

Hotels and restaurants<br />

Transport, storage and<br />

communication<br />

h<br />

i<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.44<br />

0.42<br />

0.01<br />

0.06<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.02<br />

0.08<br />

7.78<br />

7.84<br />

7.86<br />

7.86<br />

4.85<br />

4.85<br />

4.88<br />

10.98<br />

328<br />

775<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediation<br />

Real estate, rent<strong>in</strong>g and bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

activities<br />

j<br />

k<br />

—<br />

0.43<br />

0.02<br />

—<br />

0.03<br />

7.84<br />

7.86<br />

4.85<br />

9.62<br />

682<br />

Public adm<strong>in</strong>istration and defence,<br />

compulsory social security<br />

l<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.49<br />

0.55<br />

0.09<br />

0.09<br />

—<br />

—<br />

0.11<br />

0.10<br />

7.84<br />

7.80<br />

7.86<br />

7.86<br />

4.85<br />

4.85<br />

10.96<br />

12.80<br />

819<br />

938<br />

—<br />

0.63<br />

0.12<br />

—<br />

0.15<br />

7.73<br />

7.86<br />

4.85<br />

4.97<br />

344<br />

Education<br />

Health and social work<br />

Other community, social and<br />

personal service activities + Private<br />

households with employed persons<br />

+Extra-territorial organizations and<br />

bodies<br />

m<br />

n<br />

o+p+q<br />

—<br />

0.53<br />

0.08<br />

—<br />

0.10<br />

7.78<br />

7.86<br />

4.85<br />

100<br />

7029<br />

—<br />

All<br />

sectors


Bibliography<br />

<strong>Who</strong> <strong>earns</strong> <strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong> ?<br />

Addison, J. and McK. Blackburn (1999) ‘M<strong>in</strong>imum Wages and Poverty’, Industrial<br />

and Labor Relations Review, 52(3): 393-409.<br />

Brown, G., G. Giiroy and A. Kohen (1982) ‘The Effect of the M<strong>in</strong>imum Wage on<br />

Employment and Unemployment’, Journal of Economic Literature, 20: 487-528.<br />

Cahuc, P. and A. Zylberberg (2004) Labor Economics, Cambridge: MIT Press.<br />

Card, D. and A. Krueger (1995) Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the<br />

M<strong>in</strong>imum Wage, Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton: Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton University Press.<br />

Checci D. C. and Lucifora (2002) ‘<strong>Union</strong>s and Labour Market Institutions <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong>’,<br />

Economic Policy, 17(35): 363-408.<br />

Dolado, J, F. Kramarz, S. Mach<strong>in</strong>, A. Mann<strong>in</strong>g, D. Margolis, and C. Teul<strong>in</strong>gs (1996)<br />

‘The Economic Impact of M<strong>in</strong>imum Wages <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong>’, Economic Policy, 23: 319–<br />

370.<br />

Fairchild, D. (2004) ‘Does the M<strong>in</strong>imum Wage Help the Poor?’ Forum for Social<br />

Economics, 34(1-2) : 31-42.<br />

Fanti, L. and L. Gori (2011) ‘On Economic Growth and M<strong>in</strong>imum Wages’, Journal of<br />

Economics, 103(1): 59-82.<br />

Fitzenberger, B. (2009) ‚Anmerkungen zur M<strong>in</strong>destlohndebatte: Elastizitäten,<br />

Strukturparameter und Topfschlagen,‘ ZAF, 42: 85-92.<br />

Frick, J. and Krell, K. (2009) E<strong>in</strong>kommensmessungen <strong>in</strong> Haushaltspanelstudien für<br />

Deutschland: E<strong>in</strong> Vergleich von EU-SILC und SOEP, SOEPpapers, 237, Berl<strong>in</strong>,<br />

DIW.<br />

Funk, L. and H. Lesch (2006) ‘M<strong>in</strong>imum Wage Regulations <strong>in</strong> Selected <strong>Europe</strong>an<br />

Countries’, Intereconomics, 41(2): 78-92.<br />

ILO (2010) Global Wage Report 2010/11: Wage policies <strong>in</strong> times of crisis, Geneva:<br />

International Labour Office.<br />

Kaitz, H. (1970) `Experience of the Past: The National M<strong>in</strong>imum Wage', US<br />

Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics: Youth unemployment and<br />

<strong>m<strong>in</strong>imum</strong> <strong>wages</strong>, 1657.<br />

Kampelmann, S. and F. Rycx (forthcom<strong>in</strong>g) `Does <strong>in</strong>stitutional diversity account for<br />

pay rules <strong>in</strong> Germany and Belgium?' Accepted for publication <strong>in</strong> Socio-economic<br />

Review.<br />

Kennan, J. (1995) `The Elusive Effects of M<strong>in</strong>imum Wages', Journal of Economic<br />

Literature, 33(4), 1949-1965.<br />

Koeniger, W., M. Leonardi, and L. Nunziata (2007) `Labor Market Institutions and<br />

Wage Inequality', Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 60 (3), 340-356.<br />

Mach<strong>in</strong>, S. and A. Mann<strong>in</strong>g (1997) `M<strong>in</strong>imum <strong>wages</strong> and economic outcomes <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>Europe</strong>', <strong>Europe</strong>an Economic Review, 41(3-5), 733-742.<br />

Magda, I., Tojerow, I., Rycx, F., and D. Valsamis (2011) `Wage Differentials across<br />

Sectors <strong>in</strong> <strong>Europe</strong>: An East-West Comparison', Economics of Transition, 19(4),<br />

749-769.<br />

Neumark, D. and W. Wascher (2004) `M<strong>in</strong>imum Wages, Labor Market Institutions,<br />

and Youth Employment: A Cross-National Analysis', Industrial and Labor<br />

Relations Review, 57(2), 223-248.<br />

Neumark, D., M. Schweitzer and W. Wascher (2004) `M<strong>in</strong>imum Wage Effects<br />

Throughout the Wage Distribution', Journal of Human Resources, 29(2), 425-450.<br />

Neumark, D. and W. Wascher (2008) M<strong>in</strong>imum Wages, Cambridge: The MIT Press.<br />

OECD (1998) `Mak<strong>in</strong>g the Most of the M<strong>in</strong>imum: Statutory M<strong>in</strong>imum Wages,<br />

Employment and Poverty' <strong>in</strong> : Employment Outlook, Paris: OECD.<br />

Rycx, F. (2003) `Industry Wage Differentials and the Barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Regime <strong>in</strong> a<br />

Corporatist Country', International Journal of Manpower, 24(4), 347-366.<br />

Report 124<br />

63


François Rycx and Stephan Kampelmann<br />

Scarpetta, S. (1996) `Assess<strong>in</strong>g the Role of Labour Market Policies and Institutional<br />

Sett<strong>in</strong>gs on Unemployment: A Cross-Country Study', OECD Economic Studies, 26,<br />

43-98.<br />

Stigler, G. (1946) `The Economics of M<strong>in</strong>imum Wage Legislation', American<br />

Economic Review, 36, 358-365.<br />

64 Report 124


D/2012/10.574/25<br />

ISBN; 978-2-87452-271-0<br />

9 782874 522710<br />

€ 15<br />

<strong>Europe</strong>an<br />

<strong>Trade</strong> <strong>Union</strong> Institute<br />

Bd du Roi Albert II, 5<br />

1210 Brussels<br />

Belgium<br />

Tel.: +32 (0)2 224 04 70<br />

Fax: +32 (0)2 224 05 02<br />

etui@etui.org<br />

www.etui.org

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!