13.10.2013 Views

The effects of road pricing - Feweb - Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam

The effects of road pricing - Feweb - Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam

The effects of road pricing - Feweb - Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Travellers have different values <strong>of</strong> time, desired speed, and so on. First-best <strong>pricing</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong>ten makes it necessary to distinguish between different vehicle types and users<br />

(because <strong>of</strong> different marginal costs). It is important to know whether first-best<br />

congestion <strong>pricing</strong> can still be implemented, given these dimensions <strong>of</strong> heterogeneity,<br />

and if not, how second-best tolls are optimally determined. In this context a<br />

distinction is <strong>of</strong>ten made between anonymous tolling schemes (independent <strong>of</strong> vehicle<br />

type and driver) and non-anonymous (type-specific) tolls.<br />

Many studies have been conducted on the implications <strong>of</strong> the problem <strong>of</strong><br />

heterogeneity and <strong>pricing</strong>. <strong>The</strong> topics range from heterogeneity in drivers’ values <strong>of</strong><br />

time and trip-timing preferences to the heterogeneity in travel speed. Another example<br />

<strong>of</strong> a study that is <strong>of</strong> interest here is that <strong>of</strong> Verhoef and Small (2004), who consider a<br />

differentiation <strong>of</strong> tolls across parallel traffic lanes by using a static model. <strong>The</strong>y show<br />

that an anonymous toll may still be optimal on each lane separately, and efficient<br />

segregation <strong>of</strong> drivers is achieved without regulation. It should be noted that the extra<br />

gains are rather small, so that a second-best single toll applied to the entire highway<br />

does not impose much <strong>of</strong> a welfare loss. Optimal anonymous tolling may entail<br />

segregation <strong>of</strong> vehicle or driver types onto separate routes.<br />

Interactions with other sectors<br />

Imperfections in other sectors <strong>of</strong> the economy have consequences for second-best<br />

optimal <strong>pricing</strong> <strong>of</strong> transport services. Modelling the transport sector typically assumes<br />

that the rest <strong>of</strong> the economy operates under first-best conditions. Although applied<br />

with the aim <strong>of</strong> simplifying the modelling exercise, it is not very realistic. For<br />

example, the existence <strong>of</strong> distortionary taxes on other markets (especially the labour<br />

market) and income distribution (which might be suboptimal) can be motivated by<br />

governmental objectives but have implications for <strong>pricing</strong> in transport. Intersectoral<br />

issues matter because transport <strong>pricing</strong> interacts with other markets that may be<br />

strongly distorted.<br />

<strong>The</strong> existing literature on intersectoral issues shows their importance for optimal<br />

<strong>pricing</strong>: they are almost always relevant (MC-ICAM, 2002). <strong>The</strong> most relevant<br />

relation is with the labour market, which is heavily distorted: labour taxes exist<br />

mainly because the government needs revenues and for equity reasons, but strongly<br />

distort the labour-leisure choice. This implies that, whenever there is a reform in<br />

transport prices, the effect on the labour market distortion should be taken into<br />

account. Moreover, since distributional objectives can hardly be achieved by using<br />

distortionary labour taxes alone, the distributional concern will almost always be<br />

relevant in transport <strong>pricing</strong>.<br />

In this context, the spending <strong>of</strong> revenues from <strong>pricing</strong> schemes is also important for<br />

the overall success <strong>of</strong> the measure. <strong>The</strong>se revenues might be used to subsidise public<br />

transport, but also to reduce labour taxes, to increase government spending on other<br />

services, and so on. <strong>The</strong> <strong>effects</strong> for other sectors should not be neglected when<br />

looking at the <strong>effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>pricing</strong>. Parry and Bento (1999), for instance, show that the<br />

general equilibrium <strong>effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>road</strong> <strong>pricing</strong> schemes are sensitive to the spending <strong>of</strong><br />

revenues, and may deviate considerably from partial equilibrium outcomes. This may<br />

have important implications for gaining social acceptance for congestion <strong>pricing</strong><br />

schemes.<br />

2.6 Conclusions<br />

This chapter has aimed to give an overview <strong>of</strong> the economics <strong>of</strong> transport <strong>pricing</strong> and<br />

provide a basic understanding <strong>of</strong> the fundamental issues in transport <strong>pricing</strong>. It<br />

28

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!