22.01.2014 Views

Strategic motive of introducing Internet channels in a supply chain

Strategic motive of introducing Internet channels in a supply chain

Strategic motive of introducing Internet channels in a supply chain

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Strategic</strong> <strong>motive</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong><strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong> <strong>in</strong> a <strong>supply</strong> cha<strong>in</strong><br />

Lu Hsiao<br />

Department <strong>of</strong> Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Adm<strong>in</strong>istration, National Chung Hs<strong>in</strong>g University<br />

Taichung, Taiwan R.O.C.; tel: 886-04-22840571 ext. 613;<br />

fax: 886-4-22858040; e-mail: hsiaolu@dragon.nchu.edu.tw<br />

Y<strong>in</strong>g-Ju Chen<br />

Department <strong>of</strong> Industrial Eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g & Operations Research, University <strong>of</strong> California<br />

Berkeley, CA 94720; tel: 510-642-2497; fax: 510-642-1403; e-mail: chen@ieor.berkeley.edu<br />

December 2, 2012<br />

Abstract<br />

Rapid advances <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation technology <strong>in</strong> recent years have enabled both the manufacturers<br />

and the retailers to operate their own <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>. In this paper, we <strong>in</strong>vestigate<br />

the <strong>in</strong>teraction between the capabilities <strong>of</strong> <strong><strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g</strong> the <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>, the pric<strong>in</strong>g strategies,<br />

and the channel structure. We classify consumers <strong>in</strong>to two segments: Grocery shoppers<br />

attach a higher utility from purchas<strong>in</strong>g through the physical channel, whereas a priori <strong>Internet</strong><br />

shoppers prefer purchas<strong>in</strong>g onl<strong>in</strong>e. We f<strong>in</strong>d that when the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are either highly<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>itable or fairly unimportant, the manufacturer prefers to facilitate the channel separation<br />

either through his own <strong>Internet</strong> channel or the retailer’s. In the <strong>in</strong>termediate region, however,<br />

the manufacturer encroaches the grocery shoppers and steals the demand from the retailer’s<br />

physical channel. With horizontal competition between retailers, a priori symmetric retailers<br />

may adopt different channel strategies as a stable market equilibrium. The manufacturer may<br />

will<strong>in</strong>gly give up his <strong>Internet</strong> channel and leverage on the retailer competition. When the manufacturer<br />

sells through an onl<strong>in</strong>e e-tailer, <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers may be <strong>in</strong>duced to purchase through<br />

the physical channel. This reverse encroachment strategy emerges because sell<strong>in</strong>g through the<br />

e-tailer leads to a more severe double marg<strong>in</strong>alization problem.<br />

Keywords: multi-channel management, retail operations, electronic commerce, game<br />

theory.<br />

History: Received: December 2010; accepted: November 2012 by Vishal Gaur after two revisions.<br />

1


1 Introduction<br />

In recent years, the <strong>Internet</strong> channel provides a convenient and secure environment for the manufacturer/<br />

retailer and the consumers to make transactions, thereby lead<strong>in</strong>g to the “clicks-and-mortar”<br />

phenomenon. A report from the U.S. Census Bureau’s Quarterly Retail E-Commerce Sales shows<br />

that the onl<strong>in</strong>e quarterly sales has <strong>in</strong>creased to at least $33.6 billions as <strong>of</strong> second quarter <strong>of</strong> 2007<br />

(around 28% <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> 7 years). The concurrent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> the average growth rate for the total<br />

retail sales was only 4.5% (U.S. Census Bureau, 2007). Examples <strong>of</strong> the manufacturers that adopt<br />

the dual channel structure <strong>in</strong>clude, but are not limited to, lead<strong>in</strong>g firms <strong>in</strong> the computer <strong>in</strong>dustry<br />

(such as Apple, IBM, and Cisco), cosmetics manufacturers (e.g., Estee Lauder), beverage and food<br />

manufacturers (Budweiser Beer, Coca Cola, and Campbell Soup), sports goods producers (e.g.,<br />

Nike), and electronics suppliers (e.g., PalmOne, Samsung, and Sony). In addition, some lead<strong>in</strong>g<br />

U.S. retailers (e.g., Barnes & Noble, Bestbuy, Bloom<strong>in</strong>gdales, Wal-mart, Target, etc.) also have<br />

gone onl<strong>in</strong>e.<br />

However, <strong>in</strong> this <strong>Internet</strong> era, there are still a significant portion <strong>of</strong> retailers that focus exclusively<br />

on the physical <strong>channels</strong>, and a number <strong>of</strong> lead<strong>in</strong>g manufacturers <strong>in</strong>sist to sell through the<br />

direct <strong>channels</strong>. For example, the giant retailers 7-eleven and Carrefour do not provide the onl<strong>in</strong>e<br />

purchase option for the consumers. Examples that abandon the <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong> span across various<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustries, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g consumer electronics (Pricesmart), apparel (Tween Brands, Citi Trends,<br />

Dress Barn, Ross Stores), food (Spartan Stores), fabrics (Duckwall-Alco), home fashion (TJX <strong>in</strong>c.,<br />

Family Dollar), plastics (Collective Brands), pharmacy (Watsons), and grocery retailers (Pantry,<br />

Retail Enterprises, Ingles Markets, and RT-MART). 1 On the manufacturers’ side, firms that sell<br />

exclusively through <strong>in</strong>dependent retailers expand across various product categories such as Acer,<br />

Colgate, Gillette, He<strong>in</strong>z, Kellogg’s, and Tylenol.<br />

Given the consistent pr<strong>of</strong>itability and large organizations, the aforementioned manufacturers<br />

and retailers are apparently capable <strong>of</strong> operat<strong>in</strong>g their <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>; thus, these channel<br />

management decisions seem to be strategic rather than operational. Additionally, there is a large<br />

variation <strong>of</strong> the onl<strong>in</strong>e purchas<strong>in</strong>g option across different categories and locations; sometimes the<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> channel is owned by the manufacturer, whereas <strong>in</strong> other cases it is the retailer that runs<br />

the <strong>Internet</strong> channel. Operational concerns such as shipp<strong>in</strong>g costs from the manufacturers’ side<br />

and transportation costs from the consumers’ side may not provide a good answer to this variation;<br />

it is hard to expla<strong>in</strong> why consumers can order beers and soups via Budweiser’s and Campbell’s<br />

1 Most <strong>of</strong> the above retailers are selected as the top/hot retailers by Stores.com based on their dom<strong>in</strong>ant performance<br />

and/ or the remarkable growth rates (source: http://www.stores.org/Top 100 new/Top 100 land<strong>in</strong>g page.asp).<br />

2


websites, but are prohibited to purchase laptops or video game consoles directly onl<strong>in</strong>e.<br />

This paper attempts to provide an answer to when and why the manufacturer and the retailer<br />

should <strong>in</strong>troduce their <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>, given that they both are capable <strong>of</strong> do<strong>in</strong>g so and actively<br />

respond to their channel parties’ channel and pric<strong>in</strong>g decisions. In pursuit <strong>of</strong> this goal, we construct<br />

a stylized <strong>supply</strong> cha<strong>in</strong> with a manufacturer, an <strong>in</strong>dependent retailer, and a cont<strong>in</strong>uum <strong>of</strong> consumers<br />

with heterogeneous preferences. The retailer operates a physical channel and sells the products for<br />

the manufacturer to the consumers. There are two consumer segments: Grocery shoppers attach a<br />

higher (gross) utility from purchas<strong>in</strong>g the product through the physical (<strong>of</strong>fl<strong>in</strong>e) channel, whereas<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> shoppers obta<strong>in</strong> a higher utility if purchas<strong>in</strong>g onl<strong>in</strong>e.<br />

To isolate the strategic concerns <strong>of</strong> these two channel parties, we start with two benchmark<br />

scenarios with manufacturer-operated or retailer-operated <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>. When only the manufacturer<br />

is capable <strong>of</strong> <strong><strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g</strong> the <strong>Internet</strong> channel, we f<strong>in</strong>d that two strategies can emerge<br />

as the market equilibrium. If the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are sufficiently pr<strong>of</strong>itable, a natural channel<br />

separation arises: <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are <strong>in</strong>duced to purchase onl<strong>in</strong>e, whereas grocery shoppers buy<br />

<strong>in</strong> the physical channel. On the other hand, when the grocery shoppers become more important,<br />

the manufacturer shall set a low sell<strong>in</strong>g price <strong>in</strong> his <strong>Internet</strong> channel to attract the low-valuation<br />

consumers from the physical channel. This strategy allows the manufacturer to encroach the grocery<br />

shoppers without creat<strong>in</strong>g the channel conflict. When <strong>in</strong>stead only the retailer can <strong>in</strong>troduce<br />

the <strong>Internet</strong> channel, a similar channel separation strategy arises. Nevertheless, the aforementioned<br />

grocery encroachment strategy is no longer desirable. If the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are relatively important,<br />

a niche target<strong>in</strong>g strategy is implemented: the retailer abandons the physical channel and<br />

targets only the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers through her <strong>Internet</strong> channel.<br />

We then <strong>in</strong>vestigate the market equilibrium when both parties are capable <strong>of</strong> operat<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> channel. When the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are either highly pr<strong>of</strong>itable or fairly unimportant,<br />

the manufacturer prefers to facilitate the channel separation. In the <strong>in</strong>termediate region, however,<br />

the manufacturer <strong>in</strong>tends to encroach the grocery shoppers and steal the demand from the retailer’s<br />

physical channel. To understand this result, observe that when the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are highly<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>itable, the manufacturer certa<strong>in</strong>ly prefers to go direct to capture this segment. At the other<br />

extreme, when the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are fairly unimportant (compared to the grocery shoppers), it<br />

is <strong>in</strong> the manufacturer’s best <strong>in</strong>terest to delegate both <strong>channels</strong> to the retailer. In the <strong>in</strong>termediate<br />

region, the manufacturer faces two conflict<strong>in</strong>g forces. Facilitat<strong>in</strong>g channel separation via his own<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> channel <strong>in</strong>duces too much competition from the retailer, but completely delegat<strong>in</strong>g to the<br />

retailer leaves her a significant portion <strong>of</strong> revenue. In such a scenario, the manufacturer prices<br />

aggressively <strong>in</strong> his <strong>Internet</strong> channel so as to steal some grocery shoppers.<br />

3


F<strong>in</strong>ally, we consider some extended models with retail-level competition. We f<strong>in</strong>d that with<br />

retailer competition, <strong>in</strong> any equilibrium channel structure exactly two <strong>supply</strong> cha<strong>in</strong> parties <strong>in</strong>troduce<br />

their <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>. Even if the retailers are perfectly competitive, the manufacturer <strong>in</strong>tends<br />

to <strong>in</strong>duce them to both <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>, and <strong>in</strong> equilibrium both retailers will<strong>in</strong>gly<br />

do so. On the other hand, our results also suggest that even if the retailers are a priori symmetric,<br />

asymmetric channel structures may emerge as a stable market equilibrium. When the manufacturer<br />

sells through an onl<strong>in</strong>e retailer (e.g., Amazon), he may <strong>in</strong>duce <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers to purchase through<br />

the retailer’s physical channel. This reverse encroachment strategy emerges s<strong>in</strong>ce all the <strong>Internet</strong><br />

<strong>channels</strong> are “<strong>in</strong>direct,” i.e., not directly controlled by the manufacturer. The retailer’s physical<br />

channel becomes appeal<strong>in</strong>g (from the manufacturer’s viewpo<strong>in</strong>t) because the retailer <strong>in</strong>tends to<br />

set the marg<strong>in</strong> low so as to attract grocery shoppers. Consequently, the double marg<strong>in</strong>alization<br />

problem is less severe.<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ce we <strong>in</strong>vestigate the strategic choice <strong>of</strong> channel structure, our work is related to the vast<br />

literature on channel management. Earlier literature focuses on the benefit <strong>of</strong> add<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>Internet</strong><br />

channel when the firm can sell directly to the end consumers (Alba et al. (1997), Balasubramanian<br />

(1998), Bernste<strong>in</strong> et al. (2008), Kumar and Ruan (2006), Lal and Sarvary (1999), and Peterson et al.<br />

(1997)). In the context <strong>of</strong> the <strong>supply</strong> cha<strong>in</strong>, researchers typically focus exclusively on the situations<br />

<strong>in</strong> which only the manufacturer is able to <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> channel; see, e.g., Balasubramanian<br />

(1998), Cattani et al. (2006), Chiang et al. (2003), Druehl and Porteus (2005), Hsiao and Chen<br />

(2012), and Tsay and Agrawal (2004). Unlike all the aforementioned papers, we allow both the<br />

manufacturer and the retailer to <strong>in</strong>troduce their own <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>. We also highlight the<br />

<strong>in</strong>teractions between the retailer’s and e-tailer’s <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>.<br />

Our analysis regard<strong>in</strong>g the horizontal competition is related to Cattani et al. (2007), who<br />

study how competition among the <strong>Internet</strong> retailers (grocers) <strong>in</strong>fluences the channel management<br />

strategies. They document the nuance connection among the product perishability, channel structure,<br />

and competitive nature, and show that the results are robust aga<strong>in</strong>st the <strong>in</strong>clusion <strong>of</strong> capacity<br />

constra<strong>in</strong>t. As a complement <strong>of</strong> Cattani et al. (2007), we <strong>in</strong>troduce the manufacturer <strong>in</strong>to this competitive<br />

retailer context, and show that this vertical – horizontal <strong>supply</strong> cha<strong>in</strong> relationship generates<br />

various channel structures <strong>in</strong> market equilibria.<br />

The rest <strong>of</strong> this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we describe the model. Section<br />

3 derives the equilibrium behavior and compare the manufacturer’s and the retailer’s <strong>in</strong>centives<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong><strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g</strong> their <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>. Section 4 exam<strong>in</strong>es different forms <strong>of</strong> retail competition.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, we draw our conclusions <strong>in</strong> Section 5. All pro<strong>of</strong>s are <strong>in</strong> the Appendix.<br />

4


2 Model<br />

We consider a <strong>supply</strong> cha<strong>in</strong> with a manufacturer, an <strong>in</strong>dependent retailer, and a cont<strong>in</strong>uum <strong>of</strong><br />

consumers with heterogeneous preferences. The manufacturer produces the product at a constant<br />

marg<strong>in</strong>al cost, which is normalized to zero for ease <strong>of</strong> exposition. The retailer operates a physical<br />

channel and sells the products for the manufacturer to the consumers. As our primary goal is to<br />

evaluate the manufacturer’s and the retailer’s <strong>in</strong>centives <strong>of</strong> <strong><strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g</strong> an <strong>Internet</strong> channel, we allow<br />

both the manufacturer and the retailer to <strong>in</strong>troduce their own <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>. All the <strong>supply</strong><br />

cha<strong>in</strong> parties are risk neutral and therefore aim at maximiz<strong>in</strong>g their expected pr<strong>of</strong>its/utilities. The<br />

bilateral monopoly sett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> our basic framework is adopted for ease <strong>of</strong> exposition. The case with<br />

horizontal competition is <strong>in</strong>vestigated <strong>in</strong> Section 4.<br />

Consumer preferences. Each consumer is will<strong>in</strong>g to purchase at most one unit <strong>of</strong> product,<br />

and the population <strong>of</strong> consumer is normalized to 1. We categorize the consumers <strong>in</strong>to two segments<br />

that differ <strong>in</strong> their preferences towards purchas<strong>in</strong>g onl<strong>in</strong>e or <strong>of</strong>fl<strong>in</strong>e. Consumers <strong>in</strong> the first segment<br />

attach a higher (gross) utility from purchas<strong>in</strong>g the product through the physical channel, whereas<br />

consumers <strong>in</strong> the second segment obta<strong>in</strong> a higher utility if purchas<strong>in</strong>g onl<strong>in</strong>e. To model this discrepancy,<br />

we assume that a consumer whose valuation from purchas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the physical channel is<br />

v will obta<strong>in</strong> a gross utility β i v if purchas<strong>in</strong>g onl<strong>in</strong>e; the parameters {β i }’s satisfy 0 < β 1 < 1 < β 2<br />

and represent their channel preferences. For ease <strong>of</strong> presentation, <strong>in</strong> the sequel we call the first<br />

segment the “grocery shoppers,” and the second segment “<strong>Internet</strong> shoppers.” These terms <strong>in</strong>dicate<br />

the consumers’ <strong>in</strong>herent preferences over the physical and <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>.<br />

In the majority <strong>of</strong> the dual channel literature, consumers are assumed to express a lower<br />

will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay while purchas<strong>in</strong>g onl<strong>in</strong>e due to either the privacy concern or trust issues (see, e.g.,<br />

Chiang et al. (2003), Kacen et al. (2001), and Liang and Huang (1998) for the micro-foundation <strong>of</strong><br />

grocery shoppers). Nevertheless, it is possible that some consumers may <strong>in</strong>cur a higher cost upon<br />

visit<strong>in</strong>g the physical channel. This is because all the transactions can be made only when the<br />

consumers actually go to the physical retail store, whereas if purchas<strong>in</strong>g onl<strong>in</strong>e everyth<strong>in</strong>g is just<br />

“a click away.” This provides a justification <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers: the effective pay<strong>of</strong>f <strong>of</strong> a<br />

consumer may be affected by transportation cost, the possibility <strong>of</strong> see<strong>in</strong>g a stock-out, the time<br />

spent <strong>in</strong> figur<strong>in</strong>g out the exact location <strong>of</strong> the product <strong>in</strong> the shelf space, and etc.<br />

Grocery versus <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers. Although we label these two segments as grocery and<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> shoppers, their actual purchas<strong>in</strong>g behaviors shall depend on the price comparisons, as we<br />

demonstrate <strong>in</strong> Section 3. We use 1 − α and α to denote the proportions <strong>of</strong> consumers <strong>in</strong> the first<br />

and second segments. Thus, α serves as a proxy <strong>of</strong> how favorable the onl<strong>in</strong>e channel is a priori<br />

5


from the consumers’ viewpo<strong>in</strong>ts. We denote v as the “<strong>in</strong>tr<strong>in</strong>sic” valuation <strong>of</strong> a consumer, and<br />

it is assumed to be uniformly distributed over [0, V ]. This distributional assumption is made to<br />

facilitate closed-form expressions <strong>of</strong> all the equilibrium outcomes.<br />

Manufacturer’s and retailer’s strategies. Given that both the manufacturer and the<br />

retailer can <strong>in</strong>troduce their <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>, the relevant pric<strong>in</strong>g decisions are specified as follows.<br />

We use w to denote the wholesale price, p to denote the retail price <strong>in</strong> the physical channel,<br />

and w d and p d to denote the (retail) price <strong>in</strong> the manufacturer-owned and retailer-owned <strong>Internet</strong><br />

<strong>channels</strong>, respectively (the subscript d stands for the “direct” channel). Given these prices, if a<br />

consumer with valuation v purchases from the physical channel, her net utility is v − p. On the<br />

other hand, she obta<strong>in</strong>s utility β i v − w d (β i v − p d ) if purchas<strong>in</strong>g from the manufacturer-owned<br />

(retailer-owned) <strong>Internet</strong> channel. To account for the manufacturer’s additional services or brand<br />

management effort, we use f to denote the manufacturer’s operat<strong>in</strong>g cost for the <strong>Internet</strong> channel.<br />

This cost f is assumed to be reasonably small to avoid trivial results; if the operat<strong>in</strong>g cost were<br />

prohibitively high, the manufacturer would have no <strong>in</strong>centive to <strong>in</strong>troduce his <strong>Internet</strong> channel<br />

and the problem degenerates. Additionally, we use π M and π R to denote the manufacturer’s and<br />

retailer’s equilibrium pay<strong>of</strong>fs. A graphic illustration <strong>of</strong> the channel structure is given <strong>in</strong> Figure 1,<br />

and Table 1 summarizes the notation used <strong>in</strong> this paper.<br />

Figure 1: Channel structure <strong>of</strong> the basic framework.<br />

Hav<strong>in</strong>g described the channel structure and the objectives <strong>of</strong> these channel parties, we <strong>in</strong> the<br />

next section derive the equilibrium behaviors <strong>in</strong> this <strong>supply</strong> cha<strong>in</strong>.<br />

6


Notation Def<strong>in</strong>ition<br />

v consumer valuation from purchas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the physical channel<br />

β i scal<strong>in</strong>g factor for purchas<strong>in</strong>g onl<strong>in</strong>e, i = 1, 2<br />

V upper bound <strong>of</strong> v<br />

α proportion <strong>of</strong> <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers<br />

w wholesale price<br />

p retail price <strong>in</strong> the physical channel<br />

w d<br />

p d<br />

f<br />

3 Equilibrium analysis<br />

retail price <strong>in</strong> the manufacturer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> channel<br />

retail price <strong>in</strong> the retailer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> channel<br />

manufacturer’s operat<strong>in</strong>g cost for the <strong>Internet</strong> channel<br />

Table 1: Summary <strong>of</strong> notation.<br />

In this section, we <strong>in</strong>vestigate the strategic <strong>in</strong>teractions between the manufacturer and the retailer.<br />

To isolate the strategic concerns <strong>of</strong> these two channel parties, we start with two benchmark scenarios.<br />

In the first scenario, only the manufacturer is capable <strong>of</strong> operat<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>Internet</strong> channel,<br />

whereas <strong>in</strong> the second scenario the retailer is the only party that can <strong>in</strong>troduce her <strong>Internet</strong> channel;<br />

see the graphic representations <strong>of</strong> these two scenarios <strong>in</strong> Figures 2 and 3, respectively. These two<br />

scenarios serve as the benchmark cases that allow us to exam<strong>in</strong>e the manufacturer’s (retailer’s)<br />

<strong>in</strong>centive <strong>of</strong> <strong><strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g</strong> the <strong>Internet</strong> channel. Follow<strong>in</strong>g these, we then articulate the market equilibrium<br />

when both parties are capable <strong>of</strong> operat<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>Internet</strong> channel, which provides the full<br />

picture <strong>of</strong> the general model.<br />

3.1 Manufacturer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> channel<br />

Let us first consider the case <strong>in</strong> which only the manufacturer is able to operate the <strong>Internet</strong> channel.<br />

Our goal is to compare this scenario with the exist<strong>in</strong>g literature and use this benchmark to highlight<br />

the strategic role <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Internet</strong> channel for both the manufacturer and the retailer.<br />

Tim<strong>in</strong>g. The sequence <strong>of</strong> events is as follows. 1) The manufacturer determ<strong>in</strong>es whether<br />

to <strong>in</strong>troduce an <strong>Internet</strong> channel; 2) The manufacturer <strong>of</strong>fers the wholesale price to the retailer,<br />

and determ<strong>in</strong>es the price <strong>of</strong>fered to the consumers <strong>in</strong> his <strong>Internet</strong> channel if any; 3) The retailer<br />

7


Figure 2: Manufacturer-operated <strong>Internet</strong> chan-<br />

Figure 3: Retailer-operated <strong>Internet</strong> channel.<br />

nel.<br />

responds by determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the appropriate retail marg<strong>in</strong>; and 4) The consumers decide which channel<br />

to purchase the products from. S<strong>in</strong>ce the game <strong>in</strong>volves multiple rounds <strong>of</strong> strategic <strong>in</strong>teractions,<br />

we adopt the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium as our solution concept (Fudenberg and Tirole<br />

(1991)).<br />

Effective demands. By backward <strong>in</strong>duction, we first derive the effective demands <strong>in</strong> the<br />

physical channel and retailer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> channel. To this end, we shall discuss the consumers’<br />

purchas<strong>in</strong>g decisions. Note that <strong>in</strong> equilibrium it must be 0 ≤ p ≤ V and 0 ≤ w d ≤ β 2 V if there<br />

are actual transactions <strong>in</strong> both <strong>channels</strong>. First, a type-v <strong>Internet</strong> shopper buys the product on the<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> if and only if β 2 v − w d ≥ 0 and β 2 v − w d ≥ v − p. It means that v ≥ max{ w d<br />

β 2<br />

, w d−p<br />

Further, w d<br />

β 2<br />

≥ w d−p<br />

β 2 −1<br />

β 2 −1 }.<br />

if and only if w d ≤ β 2 p. A type-v <strong>Internet</strong> shopper buys the product <strong>in</strong> the<br />

physical channel if and only if v − p ≥ 0 and v − p ≥ β 2 v − w d . Thus, p ≤ v ≤ w d−p<br />

β 2 −1<br />

non-empty if and only if w d ≥ β 2 p.<br />

, and the set is<br />

Second, a type-v grocery shopper buys the product on the <strong>Internet</strong> if and only if β 1 v − w d ≥ 0<br />

and β 1 v − w d ≥ v − p. It means that w d<br />

β 1<br />

≤ v ≤ p−w d<br />

1−β 1<br />

, and the set is non-empty if and only if<br />

w d ≤ β 1 p. On the other hand, a type-v grocery shopper buys the product <strong>in</strong> the physical channel<br />

if and only if v − p ≥ 0 and v − p ≥ β 1 v − w d . It means that v ≥ max{p, p−w d<br />

1−β 1<br />

}. Further, p ≥ p−w d<br />

1−β 1<br />

if and only if w d ≥ β 1 p.<br />

Therefore, given 0 ≤ p ≤ V and 0 ≤ w d ≤ β 2 V , the demand <strong>in</strong> the physical channel, denoted<br />

8


as Q, is<br />

⎧<br />

⎪⎨<br />

Q =<br />

⎪⎩<br />

1<br />

V [(1 − α)(V − p−w d<br />

1−β 1<br />

)], if w d ≤ β 1 p<br />

1<br />

V [(1 − α)(V − p)], if β 1p ≤ w d ≤ β 2 p<br />

1<br />

V [α( w d−p<br />

β 2 −1 − p) + (1 − α)(V − p)], if w d ≥ β 2 p<br />

and the demand on the manufacturer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> channel, denoted as Q M d , is<br />

,<br />

1<br />

⎧⎪ ⎨ V [α(V − w d<br />

β 2<br />

) + (1 − α)( p−w d<br />

1−β 1<br />

− w d<br />

β 1<br />

)], if w d ≤ β 1 p<br />

Q M d = 1<br />

V<br />

⎪ [α(V − w d<br />

β 2<br />

)], if β 1 p ≤ w d ≤ β 2 p<br />

⎩ 1<br />

V [α(V − w d−p<br />

β 2 −1 )], if w d ≥ β 2 p<br />

.<br />

Manufacturer’s channel strategy. These demand functions provide a clear picture <strong>of</strong><br />

market segmentation via this <strong>supply</strong> cha<strong>in</strong>, and suggest that depend<strong>in</strong>g on the prices posted,<br />

the retailer may have access to either one consumer segment or both segments. Subsequently,<br />

we characterize the retailer’s optimal pric<strong>in</strong>g decisions us<strong>in</strong>g these demand functions as <strong>in</strong>puts.<br />

Follow<strong>in</strong>g this, we then <strong>in</strong>vestigate the manufacturer’s optimal decisions on the prices and the<br />

channel structure. While we relegate the rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g analysis to the appendix, our first result<br />

identifies the manufacturer’s channel strategy and the correspond<strong>in</strong>g equilibrium outcomes.<br />

Proposition 1. Suppose that only the manufacturer can <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> channel. There are<br />

two possible equilibrium strategies:<br />

• Channel separation strategies (CS-M and CS’-M): <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are <strong>in</strong>duced to purchase<br />

onl<strong>in</strong>e, whereas grocery shoppers buy <strong>in</strong> the physical channel (these two strategies differ only<br />

<strong>in</strong> whether the manufacturer’s pric<strong>in</strong>g decision is the <strong>in</strong>terior or corner solution);<br />

• Grocery encroachment strategy (GE-M): Only the high-valuation grocery shoppers buy <strong>in</strong> the<br />

physical channel, and others purchase onl<strong>in</strong>e.<br />

Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, the result<strong>in</strong>g equilibrium prices are:<br />

Strategy w ∗ w ∗ d<br />

p ∗<br />

GE-M<br />

CS’-M<br />

CS-M<br />

[β 2 −α(1−β 1 )(β 2 −β 1 )]V<br />

2(αβ 1 +β 2 −αβ 2 )<br />

[(2−β 1 )β 2 −α(1−β 1 )(2β1 2+2β 2−β 1 β 2 )]V<br />

2[αβ1 2+(1−α)(2−β 1)β 2 ]<br />

V<br />

2<br />

The correspond<strong>in</strong>g pay<strong>of</strong>fs are:<br />

β 1 β 2 V<br />

2(αβ 1 +β 2 −αβ 2 )<br />

β 1 (1−β 1 )V +β 1 w ∗<br />

2−β 1<br />

β 2 V<br />

2<br />

[(3−β 1 )β 2 −3α(1−β 1 )(β 2 −β 1 )]V<br />

4[αβ 1 +β 2 −αβ 2 ]<br />

wd<br />

∗<br />

β 1<br />

3V<br />

4<br />

9


Strategy π M π R<br />

GE-M<br />

CS’-M<br />

CS-M<br />

[αβ 1 (1−α)(1−β 1 )+β 2 +β 1 β 2 −αβ 2 (2−α)(1−β 1 )]V<br />

8(αβ 1 +β 2 −αβ 2 )<br />

[β 2 +α 2 (1−β 1 )(4β1 2+β 2−5β 1 β 2 )−2α(1−β 1 )(2β1 2+β 2−2β 1 β 2 )]V<br />

4[(2−β 1 )β 2 +α(β1 2−2β 2+β 1 β 2 )]<br />

(1−α+2αβ 2 )V<br />

8<br />

(1−α)(1−β 1 )V<br />

16<br />

(1−α)(1−β 1 )[β 2 +α(2β1 2−β 2−β 1 β 2 )]V<br />

4[(2−β 1 )β 2 +α(β1 2−2β 2+β 1 β 2 )] 2<br />

(1−α)V<br />

16<br />

From Proposition 1, we observe that the benefit <strong>of</strong> <strong><strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g</strong> the <strong>Internet</strong> channel primarily<br />

comes from two sources.<br />

On one hand, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>Internet</strong> channel allows the manufacturer<br />

to price discrim<strong>in</strong>ate the consumers through their self-selection behaviors.<br />

As some consumers<br />

are will<strong>in</strong>g to pay more <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Internet</strong> channel, the manufacturer can set prices appropriately to<br />

<strong>in</strong>duce them to purchase <strong>in</strong> different <strong>channels</strong>. Second, the <strong>in</strong>troduction <strong>of</strong> <strong>Internet</strong> channel allows<br />

the manufacturer to sell the products directly to the consumers <strong>in</strong>stead <strong>of</strong> by way <strong>of</strong> the retailer,<br />

thereby avoid<strong>in</strong>g the double marg<strong>in</strong>alization problem that is present <strong>in</strong> the physical channel.<br />

Given that grocery shoppers a priori prefer purchas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the physical channel and <strong>Internet</strong><br />

shoppers prefer go<strong>in</strong>g onl<strong>in</strong>e, a natural conjecture is that the manufacturer shall simply <strong>in</strong>duce them<br />

to purchase separately through these two <strong>channels</strong>. However, Proposition 1 shows that this is true<br />

only when there are sufficiently many <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers who a priori enjoy buy<strong>in</strong>g onl<strong>in</strong>e (the CS-M<br />

strategy). When a large proportion <strong>of</strong> consumers a priori prefer to purchase <strong>in</strong> the physical channel<br />

(α is small), the manufacturer shall set a low sell<strong>in</strong>g price <strong>in</strong> his <strong>Internet</strong> channel to attract the<br />

low-valuation consumers from the physical channel (the GE-M strategy). We illustrate numerically<br />

the market conditions under which the grocery encroachment strategy emerges as the equilibrium<br />

<strong>in</strong> Figure 4 (where we fix β 1 = 0.9, V = 8, and f = 1; the same parameters apply to all the<br />

subsequent figures). Notably, we can verify that all the equilibria <strong>in</strong> different regions are unique<br />

because <strong>of</strong> the sequential nature <strong>of</strong> our games. We highlight our f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g corollary.<br />

Corollary 1. Suppose that only the manufacturer can <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> channel. The grocery<br />

encroachment strategy is more likely to be implemented when the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are rather<br />

unimportant (i.e., when α and β 2 are small).<br />

Corollary 1 <strong>in</strong>dicates the precise regime for this grocery encroachment strategy to be pr<strong>of</strong>itable.<br />

To understand this result, recall that <strong>in</strong> the physical channel the retailer demands a markup and<br />

therefore the double marg<strong>in</strong>alization effect gives rise to a relatively high sell<strong>in</strong>g price. This high<br />

sell<strong>in</strong>g price <strong>in</strong>evitably forces the manufacturer to exclude some consumers with relatively low<br />

valuations. If the manufacturer is able to reta<strong>in</strong> the sell<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess through his <strong>Internet</strong> channel, he<br />

can then set a relatively low price onl<strong>in</strong>e to recoup these low-valuation consumers. This is precisely<br />

the rationale for the GE-M strategy; thus, occasionally it may dom<strong>in</strong>ate the <strong>in</strong>tuitive channel<br />

10


separation strategy. In the extreme case where the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are unimportant, the benefit<br />

from market segmentation cannot justify the hassle <strong>of</strong> operat<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>Internet</strong> channel. Consequently,<br />

the manufacturer simply abandons it and sells everyth<strong>in</strong>g through the physical channel.<br />

Note that <strong>in</strong> order to attract the low-valuation grocery shoppers to purchase onl<strong>in</strong>e, the manufacturer<br />

necessarily keeps the sell<strong>in</strong>g price low <strong>in</strong> his <strong>Internet</strong> channel. The downside <strong>of</strong> this<br />

strategy is to forgo the rent extraction from the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers. If <strong>in</strong>stead the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers<br />

constitute a highly pr<strong>of</strong>itable segment, extract<strong>in</strong>g revenue from the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers becomes the<br />

manufacturer’s primary concern. In such a scenario, the manufacturer purposely gives up those<br />

low-valuation consumers and leave all grocery shoppers <strong>in</strong> the (retailer’s) physical channel. Collectively,<br />

we observe that the manufacturer’s pric<strong>in</strong>g strategies reflect how concerned he is about<br />

different consumer segments.<br />

Figure 4: Equilibrium channel strategies<br />

with manufacturer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> channel.<br />

Figure 5: Equilibrium channel strategies with<br />

retailer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> channel.<br />

3.2 Retailer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> channel<br />

In the second scenario, the <strong>Internet</strong> channel can only be operated by the retailer. The modified<br />

sequence <strong>of</strong> events is as follows. 1) The retailer determ<strong>in</strong>es whether to <strong>in</strong>troduce an <strong>Internet</strong><br />

channel; 2) The manufacturer <strong>of</strong>fers the wholesale price to the retailer; 3) The retailer responds<br />

by determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the retail marg<strong>in</strong> for the physical channel and that for her <strong>Internet</strong> channel (if<br />

available); and 4) The consumers decide which channel to purchase the products from. Note that<br />

11


<strong>in</strong> this case, the manufacturer can only <strong>in</strong>directly affect the consumers’ purchas<strong>in</strong>g behaviors via<br />

sett<strong>in</strong>g a s<strong>in</strong>gle wholesale price.<br />

By backward <strong>in</strong>duction, the first step is to exam<strong>in</strong>e the consumers’ purchas<strong>in</strong>g decisions. As<br />

this step is similar to that <strong>in</strong> Section 3.1, we omit the details and simply summarize their collective<br />

actions as the follow<strong>in</strong>g demand functions. The demand <strong>in</strong> the physical channel Q is<br />

⎧<br />

1<br />

⎪⎨ V [(1 − α)(V − p−p d<br />

1−β 1<br />

)], if p d ≤ β 1 p<br />

Q =<br />

1<br />

V<br />

⎪⎩<br />

[(1 − α)(V − p)], if β 1p ≤ p d ≤ β 2 p ,<br />

1<br />

V [α( p d−p<br />

β 2 −1 − p) + (1 − α)(V − p)], if p d ≥ β 2 p<br />

and the demand on the <strong>Internet</strong> Q R d<br />

is<br />

1<br />

⎧⎪ ⎨ V [α(V − p d<br />

β 2<br />

) + (1 − α)( p−p d<br />

1−β 1<br />

− p d<br />

β 1<br />

)], if p d ≤ β 1 p<br />

Q R d = 1<br />

V<br />

⎪ [α(V − p d<br />

β 2<br />

)], if β 1 p ≤ p d ≤ β 2 p<br />

⎩ 1<br />

V [α(V − p d−p<br />

β 2 −1 )], if p d ≥ β 2 p<br />

.<br />

Hav<strong>in</strong>g characterized the effective demands for these <strong>channels</strong>, we can then return to the<br />

retailer’s and the manufacturer’s strategies <strong>in</strong> two stages. In the next proposition, we characterize<br />

the equilibrium strategies <strong>in</strong> this scenario, whose detailed derivations are given <strong>in</strong> the appendix.<br />

Proposition 2. Suppose that only the retailer may <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> channel. There are two<br />

possible equilibrium strategies:<br />

• Channel separation strategy (CS-R): <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are <strong>in</strong>duced to purchase onl<strong>in</strong>e, whereas<br />

grocery shoppers buy <strong>in</strong> the physical channel;<br />

• Exclusive onl<strong>in</strong>e strategy (EO-R): <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are <strong>in</strong>duced to purchase onl<strong>in</strong>e, and<br />

grocery shoppers and the physical channel are abandoned.<br />

Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, the result<strong>in</strong>g equilibrium prices are:<br />

Strategy w ∗ p ∗ p ∗ d<br />

CS-R<br />

EO-R<br />

β 2 V<br />

2[α+(1−α)β 2 ]<br />

β 2 V<br />

2<br />

> V<br />

V<br />

2 + β 2 V<br />

4[α+(1−α)β 2 ]<br />

β 2 V β<br />

2<br />

+ 2 V<br />

4[α+(1−α)β 2 ]<br />

3β 2 V<br />

4<br />

The equilibrium pay<strong>of</strong>fs and the feasibility conditions are:<br />

Strategy π M π R Condition<br />

CS-R<br />

EO-R<br />

β 2 V<br />

8[α+(1−α)β 2 ]<br />

αβ 2 V<br />

8<br />

[β 2 +4α(1−α)(β 2 −1) 2 ]V<br />

16[α+(1−α)β 2 ]<br />

α ≤ 1<br />

β 2 −1<br />

αβ 2 V<br />

16<br />

α ≥ 1<br />

β 2 −1<br />

12


Proposition 2 identifies two strategies for the retailer to differentiate the consumers based<br />

on their heterogeneous preferences <strong>in</strong> the presence <strong>of</strong> retailer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> channel. When the<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are not very pr<strong>of</strong>itable (i.e., with a small population or when their average<br />

valuation is not very high), the retailer will implement the natural channel separation strategy:<br />

<strong>in</strong>duc<strong>in</strong>g the first consumer segment to purchase <strong>in</strong> the physical channel and the second consumer<br />

segment to shop onl<strong>in</strong>e. As aforementioned, this strategy facilitates the price discrim<strong>in</strong>ation through<br />

different <strong>channels</strong>. When the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are relatively important, the retailer now <strong>in</strong>stead<br />

uses a niche target<strong>in</strong>g strategy. Incidentally, the equilibrium price under this strategy (EO-R)<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicates that the retailer effectively abandons the physical channel: as p ∗ > V , she sets a high<br />

sell<strong>in</strong>g price so that only the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers purchase <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Internet</strong> channel.<br />

It is worth mention<strong>in</strong>g that unlike the case with the manufacturer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> channel,<br />

here the retailer has no <strong>in</strong>tention to implicitly split the consumers from the same segment, i.e., the<br />

grocery encroachment strategy is no longer desirable. While the manufacturer <strong>in</strong>tends to use his<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> channel to subsidize the downside <strong>of</strong> the double marg<strong>in</strong>alization problem, this <strong>in</strong>itiative is<br />

absent when the retailer coord<strong>in</strong>ates the sell<strong>in</strong>g prices over different <strong>channels</strong>. We hereby highlight<br />

this result as a corollary and provide a numerical illustration <strong>in</strong> Figure 5.<br />

Corollary 2. Suppose that only the retailer can <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> channel. The exclusive<br />

onl<strong>in</strong>e strategy is more likely to be implemented when the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are rather important<br />

(i.e., when α and β 2 are large). In addition, <strong>in</strong> equilibrium grocery shoppers never purchase onl<strong>in</strong>e,<br />

whereas <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers never go to the physical channel.<br />

Incidentally, this niche target<strong>in</strong>g strategy <strong>in</strong> Corollary 2 can never emerge as an equilibrium<br />

outcome with only the manufacturer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> channel. This is because compared with this<br />

target<strong>in</strong>g strategy, the manufacturer also benefits from <strong>in</strong>duc<strong>in</strong>g some grocery shoppers to purchase<br />

<strong>in</strong> the physical channel <strong>in</strong> the first scenario, even if he has to share the revenue with the retailer.<br />

Thus, completely abandon<strong>in</strong>g the physical channel is not preferable from the manufacturer’s perspective.<br />

3.3 Both the manufacturer and the retailer can <strong>in</strong>troduce <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong><br />

Hav<strong>in</strong>g articulated the benefits and consequences <strong>of</strong> <strong><strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g</strong> the <strong>Internet</strong> channel for the manufacturer<br />

and the retailer, we now <strong>in</strong>corporate the possibility that both parties are able to operate<br />

<strong>in</strong>dependent <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>. The sequence <strong>of</strong> events follows the above two subsections except<br />

13


that at the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g the manufacturer and the retailer determ<strong>in</strong>e simultaneously whether to <strong>in</strong>troduce<br />

an <strong>Internet</strong> channel. The possible equilibrium strategies are characterized <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

proposition.<br />

Proposition 3. When both the manufacturer and the retailer can sell the products through their<br />

own <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>, there are four possible equilibrium strategies:<br />

• Grocery encroachment strategy (GE-M): Only the high-valuation grocery shoppers buy <strong>in</strong> the<br />

physical channel, and others purchase <strong>in</strong> the manufacturer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> channel.<br />

• Channel separation strategy with Retailer’s <strong>Internet</strong> channel (CS-R): <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are<br />

<strong>in</strong>duced to purchase <strong>in</strong> the retailer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> channel, whereas grocery shoppers buy <strong>in</strong><br />

the physical channel;<br />

• Channel separation strategies (CS-M, CS’-M): <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are <strong>in</strong>duced to purchase<br />

onl<strong>in</strong>e, whereas grocery shoppers buy <strong>in</strong> the physical channel.<br />

From Proposition 3, we observe that strategy EO-R is no longer susta<strong>in</strong>able. Recollect that<br />

<strong>in</strong> the absence <strong>of</strong> manufacturer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> channel, the exclusive onl<strong>in</strong>e (EO-R) strategy <strong>in</strong>dicates<br />

that the retailer may abandon the physical channel and set a high price to serve only those<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> shoppers. When the manufacturer is also capable <strong>of</strong> operat<strong>in</strong>g his <strong>Internet</strong> channel, this<br />

niche target<strong>in</strong>g strategy may ignite the manufacturer’s counteraction. S<strong>in</strong>ce the retailer attempts<br />

to give up the physical channel, the manufacturer will certa<strong>in</strong>ly undercut the retailer’s price to<br />

capture all the consumers. Push<strong>in</strong>g this idea further, the manufacturer can raise the wholesale<br />

price to deactivate both the physical channel and the retailer’s <strong>Internet</strong> channel. To counteract the<br />

retailer’s exclusive onl<strong>in</strong>e strategy, the manufacturer can meticulously design the wholesale price<br />

and operate his <strong>Internet</strong> channel to facilitate the maximum benefit <strong>of</strong> channel separation. This<br />

provides an economic rationale for why the retailer always ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>s her physical channel. In addition<br />

to keep<strong>in</strong>g her core competence (as the conventional wisdom), the retailer strategically uses<br />

this physical channel to avoid the v<strong>in</strong>dictive behavior from her <strong>supply</strong> cha<strong>in</strong> partner.<br />

Notably, Proposition 3 suggests that the manufacturer may will<strong>in</strong>gly give up sell<strong>in</strong>g onl<strong>in</strong>e, but<br />

nevertheless his capability <strong>of</strong> operat<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>Internet</strong> channel still has a direct impact on the market<br />

equilibrium. Thus, reta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g this capability has a strategic value, as it allows the manufacturer to<br />

counterbalance the retailer’s pric<strong>in</strong>g power. This result is somewhat related to a recent <strong>in</strong>dustry<br />

report by Brohan (2012), who explicitly mentions that most manufacturers that operate their<br />

14


<strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong> do not really generate additional sales that live up to the market’s expectation.<br />

As Brohan (2012) expla<strong>in</strong>s, this phenomenon occurs only to those manufacturers who rely on<br />

their long-term retailer partners; it can therefore be regarded as a consequence <strong>of</strong> manufacturers’<br />

attempts to avoid the channel conflict.<br />

Figure 6: Equilibrium channel strategies <strong>in</strong> the full model.<br />

Given the above discussions, a natural question is when these strategies emerge as the market<br />

equilibria <strong>in</strong> different scenarios. While Proposition 3 lays out the precise conditions that identify<br />

the optimal strategies among the three via rout<strong>in</strong>e algebra, we f<strong>in</strong>d it more illustrative to show<br />

this graphically <strong>in</strong> Figure 6. From Figure 6, we observe that when the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are either<br />

highly pr<strong>of</strong>itable (when α and β 2 are large) or fairly unimportant (when α and β 2 are small), the<br />

manufacturer prefers to facilitate the channel separation either through his own <strong>Internet</strong> channel<br />

or the retailer’s. In the <strong>in</strong>termediate region, however, the manufacturer <strong>in</strong>tends to encroach the<br />

grocery shoppers and steal the demand from the retailer’s physical channel. 2 To understand this<br />

result, observe that when the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are highly pr<strong>of</strong>itable, the manufacturer certa<strong>in</strong>ly<br />

prefers to go direct to capture this segment. Thus, us<strong>in</strong>g his <strong>Internet</strong> channel is the most effective<br />

way to avoid double marg<strong>in</strong>alization and materialize the benefit. At the other extreme, when the<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are fairly unimportant (compared to the grocery shoppers), the manufacturer’s<br />

primary goal is to avoid channel conflict. In this case, it is <strong>in</strong> the manufacturer’s best <strong>in</strong>terest<br />

2 We choose to vary β 2 because the conditions that dist<strong>in</strong>guish different regimes (strategies) all depend on β 2 .<br />

Thus, through this one-dimensional change, we can conveniently illustrate all possible strategies <strong>in</strong> one figure for a<br />

fixed set <strong>of</strong> other parameters. We have also conducted an alternative numerical experiment where we change β 1 and<br />

β 2 simultaneously. We f<strong>in</strong>d that the effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g β 1 is essentially the same as that <strong>of</strong> decreas<strong>in</strong>g β 2.<br />

15


to delegate both <strong>channels</strong> to the retailer. In the <strong>in</strong>termediate region, the manufacturer faces two<br />

conflict<strong>in</strong>g forces. Facilitat<strong>in</strong>g channel separation via his own <strong>Internet</strong> channel <strong>in</strong>duces too much<br />

competition from the retailer, whereas completely delegat<strong>in</strong>g to the retailer leaves a significant<br />

portion <strong>of</strong> revenue to the retailer’s side. In such a scenario, the manufacturer sets a low price <strong>in</strong> his<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> channel so as to attract some low-valuation grocery shoppers to purchase onl<strong>in</strong>e (strategy<br />

GE-M). This low-price strategy allows the manufacturer to steal the obscure market <strong>of</strong> grocery<br />

shoppers at no cost <strong>of</strong> channel conflict.<br />

4 Discussions<br />

In this section, we consider some variants <strong>of</strong> our model characteristics. 3 To avoid repetition, we<br />

will only highlight the primary differences and focus on the new implications that are absent <strong>in</strong> the<br />

basic framework.<br />

4.1 Retailer competition<br />

In our basic model, we assume away the horizontal competition and study the bilateral monopoly<br />

sett<strong>in</strong>g. However, <strong>in</strong> reality, the manufacturer typically sells through multiple retailers that compete<br />

aga<strong>in</strong>st each other. In such a scenario, there are multiple physical <strong>channels</strong>, and each retailer can<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>e whether to <strong>in</strong>troduce her own <strong>Internet</strong> channel. A natural question is therefore how the<br />

equilibrium channel structure is <strong>in</strong>fluenced by the horizontal competition.<br />

To address this question, we consider an extended model <strong>in</strong> which the manufacturer sells<br />

through two <strong>in</strong>dependent retailers, <strong>in</strong>dexed as 1 and 2. We allow both retailer (as well as the<br />

manufacturer) to <strong>in</strong>troduce their own <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>. The sequence <strong>of</strong> events proceeds as follows.<br />

1) The manufacturer and the retailers simultaneously determ<strong>in</strong>e whether to <strong>in</strong>troduce an <strong>Internet</strong><br />

channel; 2) The manufacturer <strong>of</strong>fers the wholesale price to the retailers; 3) The manufacturer and<br />

the retailers simultaneously determ<strong>in</strong>e the sell<strong>in</strong>g prices <strong>of</strong> their own <strong>channels</strong> (if available); and 4)<br />

The consumers decide which channel to purchase the products from. Figure 7 presents a graphic<br />

illustration <strong>of</strong> the possible channel structure.<br />

As <strong>in</strong> Section 3, we can also exam<strong>in</strong>e the consumers’ purchas<strong>in</strong>g decisions and express them <strong>in</strong><br />

the form <strong>of</strong> effective demands for different <strong>channels</strong>. Afterwards, we then use backward <strong>in</strong>duction<br />

to characterize the equilibrium strategies <strong>of</strong> the manufacturer and the retailers. These detailed<br />

3 We thank an anonymous reviewer for suggest<strong>in</strong>g these extensions.<br />

16


Figure 7: Channel structure under retailer competition.<br />

derivations are given <strong>in</strong> the appendix, and we summarize the ma<strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs below.<br />

Proposition 4. With retailer competition, <strong>in</strong> any equilibrium channel structure, exactly two <strong>supply</strong><br />

cha<strong>in</strong> parties <strong>in</strong>troduce their <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>. Moreover, given any primitive parameter comb<strong>in</strong>ation,<br />

it is always an equilibrium that the manufacturer abandons his <strong>Internet</strong> channel and both<br />

retailers <strong>in</strong>troduce their own.<br />

Figure 8: Equilibrium channel strategies with retailer competition.<br />

Proposition 4 shows that retailer competition can significantly <strong>in</strong>fluence the equilibrium channel<br />

structure, and it gives rise to various k<strong>in</strong>ds <strong>of</strong> channel structures we observe <strong>in</strong> practice. A<br />

notable observation is that even if the retailers are perfectly competitive, the manufacturer <strong>in</strong>tends<br />

to <strong>in</strong>duce them to both <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>, and <strong>in</strong> equilibrium both retailers will-<br />

17


<strong>in</strong>gly do so. To elaborate the <strong>in</strong>tuition beh<strong>in</strong>d this, recollect that the economic rationale for the<br />

manufacturer to <strong>in</strong>troduce his own <strong>Internet</strong> channel is to fight aga<strong>in</strong>st the double marg<strong>in</strong>alization<br />

problem. Thus, this direct channel allows the manufacturer to bypass the retailer’s mark-up and<br />

at the same time <strong>in</strong>duces the retailer to reduce the sell<strong>in</strong>g price <strong>in</strong> the physical channel. In the<br />

presence <strong>of</strong> retailer competition, however, this direct channel is no longer required. Specifically, the<br />

<strong>in</strong>tense competition between the retailers effectively elim<strong>in</strong>ates the double marg<strong>in</strong>alization problem<br />

and the price competition automatically drives down the sell<strong>in</strong>g prices <strong>in</strong> the physical <strong>channels</strong>. In<br />

light <strong>of</strong> this, the manufacturer does not need to go through the hassle <strong>of</strong> open<strong>in</strong>g his own <strong>Internet</strong><br />

channel. This might expla<strong>in</strong> why <strong>in</strong> reality some lead<strong>in</strong>g manufacturers (such as Acer, Colgate,<br />

Gillette, He<strong>in</strong>z, Kellogg’s, and Tylenol) do not <strong>of</strong>fer their <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>.<br />

On the other hand, our results also suggest that even if the retailers are a priori symmetric,<br />

asymmetric channel structures may emerge as a stable market equilibrium. This possibility prevails<br />

even if these retailers are sell<strong>in</strong>g the same products and compete head-to-head for the end consumers.<br />

The primary reason is that when the opponent has already opened the <strong>Internet</strong> channel, <strong><strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g</strong><br />

another one does not mitigate the competition and therefore is not beneficial for the retailer. Thus,<br />

we document the possibility <strong>of</strong> asymmetric equilibrium channel structure. Our analysis provides a<br />

partial answer to the prevalent phenomenon that a significant portion <strong>of</strong> retailers focus exclusively<br />

on the physical <strong>channels</strong> <strong>in</strong> this <strong>Internet</strong> era. As aforementioned <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>troduction, this applies<br />

to the follow<strong>in</strong>g retailers: 7-eleven, Carrefour, Pricesmart, Tween Brands, Citi Trends, Dress Barn,<br />

Ross Stores, Spartan Stores, Duckwall-Alco, TJX <strong>in</strong>c., Family Dollar, Collective Brands, Watsons,<br />

Pantry, Retail Enterprises, Ingles Markets, and RT-MART.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, we <strong>of</strong>fer a graphic illustration <strong>of</strong> when these channel structures may emerge as the<br />

market equilibrium <strong>in</strong> Figure 8. From Figure 8, we observe that the manufacturer is will<strong>in</strong>g to give<br />

up his <strong>Internet</strong> channel only when the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are relatively less important (when α and<br />

β 2 are both small). On the other hand, the aforementioned asymmetric channel structures appear<br />

<strong>in</strong> various scenarios. The economic forces have been elaborated <strong>in</strong> Section 3.3, as the manufacturer’s<br />

concern about the consequence <strong>of</strong> retailers’ counteractions is more pronounced with a less important<br />

segment <strong>of</strong> <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers. Notably, even if the double marg<strong>in</strong>alization problem <strong>in</strong> the physical<br />

<strong>channels</strong> is largely elim<strong>in</strong>ated by the horizontal competition, the channel conflict concern rema<strong>in</strong>s<br />

salient.<br />

18


4.2 Sell<strong>in</strong>g through an e-tailer<br />

Figure 9: Channel structure with an e-tailer.<br />

We now consider the scenario where<strong>in</strong> the manufacturer sells through an onl<strong>in</strong>e retailer (e.g., Amazon).<br />

In this scenario, the modified sequence <strong>of</strong> events becomes the follow<strong>in</strong>g. 1) The manufacturer<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>es the wholesale prices w and w d for the physical and <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>, respectively. 2)<br />

The retailer and e-tailer determ<strong>in</strong>e their sell<strong>in</strong>g prices p and p d simultaneously. 3) Consumers make<br />

their purchas<strong>in</strong>g decisions. When both the manufacturer and the retailer can <strong>in</strong>troduce <strong>Internet</strong><br />

<strong>channels</strong>, <strong>in</strong> stage 2) the retailer also determ<strong>in</strong>es her onl<strong>in</strong>e sell<strong>in</strong>g price.<br />

The primary departure from our basic framework is that both onl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>channels</strong> are <strong>in</strong> a sense<br />

“<strong>in</strong>direct:” one operated by the retailer, whereas the other operated by the e-tailer. Figure 9<br />

presents a graphic illustration <strong>of</strong> the channel structure <strong>in</strong> this modified sett<strong>in</strong>g. As we verify <strong>in</strong> the<br />

appendix, most <strong>of</strong> the equilibrium properties <strong>in</strong> the basic framework are preserved. Nonetheless, a<br />

new equilibrium channel strategy may arise, as highlighted <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g proposition.<br />

Proposition 5. Suppose that the manufacturer sells through an e-tailer and a dual-channel retailer.<br />

In equilibrium, the manufacturer may <strong>in</strong>duce <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers to purchase through the retailer’s<br />

physical channel.<br />

Proposition 5 suggests that the manufacturer now has a stronger <strong>in</strong>centive to sell through the<br />

physical channel. In our basic framework, the manufacturer may encroach the grocery shoppers<br />

via his own <strong>Internet</strong> channel (the GE-M strategy). This is because the direct channel effectively<br />

bypasses the retailer’s mark-up. Nevertheless, when the <strong>Internet</strong> channel is facilitated by the e-<br />

19


tailer, sell<strong>in</strong>g onl<strong>in</strong>e does not allow the manufacturer to escape from the double marg<strong>in</strong>alization<br />

problem. This substantially changes the manufacturer’s channel management strategy, as now the<br />

manufacturer captures some <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers via the physical channel. The retailer’s physical<br />

channel becomes appeal<strong>in</strong>g (from the manufacturer’s viewpo<strong>in</strong>t) because the retailer <strong>in</strong>tends to<br />

set the marg<strong>in</strong> low so as to attract grocery shoppers. Consequently, the double marg<strong>in</strong>alization<br />

problem is less severe. In contrast, the e-tailer targets <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers who have high valuations<br />

upon onl<strong>in</strong>e shopp<strong>in</strong>g. Thus, the e-tailer is more <strong>in</strong>cl<strong>in</strong>ed to set a high marg<strong>in</strong>. We have also<br />

verified via numerical experiments that such a new strategy <strong>in</strong>deed emerges as an equilibrium <strong>in</strong><br />

some situations. We omit the details here to avoid repetition.<br />

5 Conclusions<br />

In this paper, we exam<strong>in</strong>e the rationale for <strong><strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g</strong> the <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong> <strong>of</strong> the manufacturer<br />

and the retailer. We identify three equilibrium strategies that feature channel separation, consumer<br />

encroachment, and exclusive sell<strong>in</strong>g. When the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers are either highly pr<strong>of</strong>itable or<br />

fairly unimportant, the manufacturer prefers to facilitate the channel separation either through<br />

his own <strong>Internet</strong> channel or the retailer’s. In the <strong>in</strong>termediate region, however, the manufacturer<br />

<strong>in</strong>tends to encroach the grocery shoppers and steal the demand from the retailer’s physical channel.<br />

With horizontal competition between the retailers, a priori symmetric retailers may adopt different<br />

channel strategies as a stable market equilibrium. Furthermore, the manufacturer may will<strong>in</strong>gly<br />

give up his <strong>Internet</strong> channel and leverage on the retailer competition. When the manufacturer<br />

sells through an onl<strong>in</strong>e retailer, he may <strong>in</strong>duce <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers to purchase through the retailer’s<br />

physical channel. Our results provide an economic rationale for the apparent discrepancy among<br />

various market phenomena <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Internet</strong> channel adoptions.<br />

Our analysis reveals several economic rationales for <strong><strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g</strong>/abandon<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>.<br />

Naturally, there are other reasons why the retailers’ <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong> exist, such as one-stop<br />

shopp<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> multiple products, loyalty programs, and etc. While these issues have their own merits<br />

and perhaps warrant a separate analysis, it seems rather difficult to <strong>in</strong>corporate all the possible<br />

<strong>in</strong>gredients <strong>in</strong> a s<strong>in</strong>gle model. Nevertheless, one-stop shopp<strong>in</strong>g and loyalty programs are two crucial<br />

components for the success <strong>of</strong> prevalent retailer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>, and they rema<strong>in</strong> research<br />

priority. In addition, while our model excludes all the possible restrictions on the pric<strong>in</strong>g strategies,<br />

there are situations <strong>in</strong> which the manufacturer may be forced to use the same (retail) price <strong>in</strong> the<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> channel as the wholesale/retail price <strong>in</strong> the physical channel. As aforementioned, the retail<br />

20


price <strong>in</strong> the manufacturer’s <strong>Internet</strong> channel may be necessarily higher than the wholesale price<br />

<strong>in</strong> the physical channel <strong>in</strong> order to elim<strong>in</strong>ate the retailer’s arbitrage opportunity (Chiang et al.<br />

(2003)). The (retail) prices <strong>in</strong> different <strong>channels</strong> may be set equal to alleviate the channel conflict<br />

(Cattani et al. (2006)). These restrictions on the pric<strong>in</strong>g strategy <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Internet</strong> channel def<strong>in</strong>itely<br />

affect the manufacturer’s/ retailer’s <strong>in</strong>centive to <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> channel.<br />

Acknowledgement<br />

We thank Vishal Gaur (the department editor) and the review team for the detailed comments<br />

and many valuable suggestions that have significantly improved the quality <strong>of</strong> the paper. We have<br />

also benefited from the discussions with Gangshu Cai, Jane Gu, Daniel L<strong>in</strong>, Olga Perdikaki, Jiong<br />

Sun, Chi-Cheng Wu, Wenqiang Xiao, and Xuy<strong>in</strong>g Zhao. Hsiao acknowledges the f<strong>in</strong>ancial support<br />

by the National Science Council <strong>in</strong> Taiwan (NSC 98-2410-H-005-005). All rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g errors are our<br />

own.<br />

References<br />

Alba, J., J. Lynch, B. Weitz, C. Janiszewski, R. Lutz, A. Sawyer, and S. Wood (1997). Interactive<br />

home shopp<strong>in</strong>g: Consumer, retailer, and manufacturer <strong>in</strong>centives to participate <strong>in</strong> electronic<br />

marketplaces. Journal <strong>of</strong> Market<strong>in</strong>g 61 (3), 38–53.<br />

Balasubramanian, S. (1998). Mail versus mall: A strategic analysis <strong>of</strong> competition between direct<br />

marketers and conventional retailers. Market<strong>in</strong>g Science 17 (3), 181–195.<br />

Bernste<strong>in</strong>, F., J. Song, and X. Zheng (2008). Bricks-and-mortar vs.clicks-and-mortar: An equilibrium<br />

analysis. European Journal <strong>of</strong> Operational Research 187 (3), 671–690.<br />

Brohan, M. (2012). Top 500 manufacturers can do more to run at full capacity<br />

onl<strong>in</strong>e: Channel conflict rema<strong>in</strong>s an issue. May 11, 2012, InterentRetailer.com;<br />

http://www.<strong>in</strong>ternetretailer.com/2012/05/11/top-500-brand-manufacturers-can-domore-onl<strong>in</strong>e<br />

(retrived 12/02/2012).<br />

Cattani, K., H. Heese, W. Gilland, and J. Swam<strong>in</strong>athan (2006). Boil<strong>in</strong>g frogs: Pric<strong>in</strong>g strategies for<br />

a manufacturer add<strong>in</strong>g a direct channel that competes with the traditional channel. Production<br />

and Operations Management 15 (1), 40–56.<br />

21


Cattani, K., O. Perdikaki, and A. Marucheck (2007). The perishability <strong>of</strong> onl<strong>in</strong>e grocers. Decision<br />

Sciences 38 (2), 329–355.<br />

Chiang, W., D. Chhajed, and J. Hess (2003). Direct market<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong>direct pr<strong>of</strong>its: A strategic analysis<br />

<strong>of</strong> dual-channel <strong>supply</strong>-cha<strong>in</strong> design. Management Science 49 (1), 1–20.<br />

Druehl, C. and E. Porteus (2005). Onl<strong>in</strong>e versus <strong>of</strong>fl<strong>in</strong>e price competition: Market outcomes and<br />

the effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternet shopp<strong>in</strong>g penetration. Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper. University <strong>of</strong> Maryland.<br />

Fudenberg, D. and J. Tirole (1991). Game Theory. Cambridge, Massachussetts: The MIT Press.<br />

Hsiao, L. and Y.-J. Chen (2012). The perils <strong>of</strong> sell<strong>in</strong>g onl<strong>in</strong>e: Manufacturer competition, channel<br />

conflict, and consumer preferences. Market<strong>in</strong>g Letters. Forthcom<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Kacen, J., J. Hess, and W. Chiang (2001). Shoppers attitudes toward onl<strong>in</strong>e and traditional grocery<br />

stores. Work<strong>in</strong>g paper, University <strong>of</strong> Ill<strong>in</strong>ois, Champaign, IL.<br />

Kumar, N. and R. Ruan (2006). On manufacturers complement<strong>in</strong>g the traditional retail channel<br />

with a direct onl<strong>in</strong>e channel. Quantitative Market<strong>in</strong>g and Economics 4 (3), 289–323.<br />

Lal, R. and M. Sarvary (1999). When and how is the <strong>in</strong>ternet likely to decrease price competition?<br />

Market<strong>in</strong>g Science 18 (4), 485–503.<br />

Liang, T. and J. Huang (1998). An empirical study on consumer acceptance <strong>of</strong> products <strong>in</strong> electronic<br />

markets: A transaction cost model. Decision Support Systems 24 (1), 29–43.<br />

Peterson, R., S. Balasubramanian, and B. Bronnenberg (1997). Explor<strong>in</strong>g the implications <strong>of</strong> the<br />

<strong>in</strong>ternet for consumer market<strong>in</strong>g. Journal <strong>of</strong> the Academy <strong>of</strong> Market<strong>in</strong>g Science 25 (4), 329–346.<br />

Tsay, A. and N. Agrawal (2004). Channel conflict and coord<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>in</strong> the e-commerce age. Production<br />

and Operations Management 13 (1), 93–110.<br />

22


Technical appendix for “<strong>Strategic</strong> <strong>motive</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong><strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong> <strong>in</strong><br />

a <strong>supply</strong> cha<strong>in</strong>”<br />

In this appendix, we provide the detailed derivations <strong>of</strong> the equilibrium analysis. We f<strong>in</strong>d<br />

it convenient to organize the appendix based on the scenarios rather than the propositions and<br />

corollaries. Thus, <strong>in</strong> the sequel we shall start with our basic framework with bilateral monopolies,<br />

and then exam<strong>in</strong>e the cases with retailer competition and e-tailer. In what follows, we will apply the<br />

first-order conditions to obta<strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terior solutions <strong>in</strong> various scenarios, and then verify whether<br />

these <strong>in</strong>terior solutions are <strong>in</strong>deed feasible. We will also <strong>in</strong>vestigate all the possible corner solutions.<br />

Regard<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>terior solutions, the second-order conditions all hold automatically as (most <strong>of</strong>) the<br />

expected pr<strong>of</strong>it expressions are quadratically concave. For brevity we omit the detailed verifications<br />

<strong>of</strong> the second-order conditions.<br />

A<br />

Basic framework: bilateral monopolies<br />

In our basic framework, we divide our analysis <strong>in</strong>to the follow<strong>in</strong>g four subgames: (I) Neither party<br />

can <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> channel; (II) Only the manufacturer can <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> channel;<br />

(III) Only the retailer can <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> channel; and (IV) Both parties can <strong>in</strong>troduce the<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>.<br />

A.1 Neither party can <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> channel<br />

In this case, the only transactions take place <strong>in</strong> the physical channel. By backward <strong>in</strong>duction, we<br />

first start with the consumers’ choices, and then return to the retailer’s pric<strong>in</strong>g decision. F<strong>in</strong>ally,<br />

we exam<strong>in</strong>e the manufacturer’s optimal wholesale price. Given the sell<strong>in</strong>g price p, a consumer buys<br />

the product if and only if v − p ≥ 0. Thus, the retailer’s pr<strong>of</strong>it is π R = (p − w) 1 V<br />

(V − p). From<br />

the first-order conditions, we have p ∗ = V +w<br />

2<br />

and Q ∗ = V −w<br />

2V<br />

. This gives rise to the manufacturer’s<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>it: π M = w V −w<br />

2V . The first-order condition then leads to the optimal wholesale price w∗ = V 2 .<br />

In sum, when neither party <strong>in</strong>troduces the <strong>Internet</strong> channel,<br />

w ∗ = V 2 , p∗ = 3V 4 , Q∗ = 1 4 , π M = V 8 , and π R = V 16 .<br />

23


A.2 Only the manufacturer can <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> channel<br />

As the consumers’ purchas<strong>in</strong>g decisions have been discussed <strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> text (via the demand<br />

functions Q and Q M d<br />

), below we characterize the retailer’s optimal pric<strong>in</strong>g decisions. Follow<strong>in</strong>g this,<br />

we then <strong>in</strong>vestigate the manufacturer’s optimal decisions on the prices and the channel structure.<br />

A.2.1<br />

Retailer’s optimal strategy<br />

Because the retailer does not <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> channel, her pr<strong>of</strong>it is π R = (p−w)Q. If w > V ,<br />

it is obvious that the retailer does not sell any products; thus, π R = 0. Therefore, the follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

discussions focus on the case <strong>in</strong> which 0 ≤ w ≤ V and 0 ≤ w d ≤ β 2 V .<br />

Given w and w d , the<br />

retailer has three pric<strong>in</strong>g strategies, depend<strong>in</strong>g on how her sell<strong>in</strong>g price compares with that <strong>in</strong> the<br />

manufacturer-owned <strong>Internet</strong> channel: (i) w d ≤ β 1 p, (ii) β 1 p ≤ w d ≤ β 2 p, and (iii) w d ≥ β 2 p.<br />

First, consider the case (i) w d ≤ β 1 p. Under this strategy,<br />

π R = (p − w) 1 V [(1 − α)(V − p − w d<br />

1 − β 1<br />

)].<br />

From the first-order condition, we have p ∗ = (1−β 1)V +w+w d<br />

2<br />

. Note that w d ≤ β 1 p ∗ if and only if<br />

w d ≤ β 1(1−β 1 )V +β 1 w<br />

2−β 1<br />

. Under this condition, p ∗ ≤ V also holds. Second, <strong>in</strong> the case (ii) β 1 p ≤ w d ≤<br />

β 2 p,<br />

π R = (p − w) 1 [(1 − α)(V − p)].<br />

V<br />

From the first-order condition, we have p ∗ = V + w . β 1 p ∗ ≤ w d ≤ β 2 p ∗ if and only if β 1(V + w)<br />

≤<br />

2<br />

2<br />

w d ≤ β 2(V + w)<br />

.<br />

2<br />

Third, <strong>in</strong> the case (iii) w d ≥ β 2 p,<br />

π R = (p − w) 1 V [α(w d − p<br />

β 2 − 1<br />

− p) + (1 − α)(V − p)].<br />

It is verifiable that this strategy is dom<strong>in</strong>ated from the manufacturer’s perspective. Thus, while<br />

analyz<strong>in</strong>g the equilibrium strategies, it suffices to focus on cases (i) and (ii).<br />

A.2.2<br />

Manufacturer’s optimal strategy<br />

Next, we return to the manufacturer’s decision mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the first stage.<br />

We shall discuss the<br />

optimal pric<strong>in</strong>g strategies case by case, depend<strong>in</strong>g on how the wholesale price w and the sell<strong>in</strong>g<br />

24


price w d <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Internet</strong> channel fare. Note that<br />

β 1 (1 − β 1 )V + β 1 w<br />

≤ β 1(V + w)<br />

2 − β 1 2<br />

≤ β 2(V + w)<br />

.<br />

2<br />

Therefore, the manufacturer has three strategies: 1) GE-M: w d ≤ β 1(1−β 1 )V +β 1 w<br />

; 2) CS’-M:<br />

β 1 (1−β 1 )V +β 1 w<br />

2−β 1<br />

≤ w d ≤ β 1(V +w)<br />

2<br />

; 3) CS-M: β 1(V +w)<br />

2<br />

≤ w d ≤ β 2(V +w)<br />

2<br />

.<br />

First, under GE-M, p ∗ = (1−β 1)V +w+w d<br />

2<br />

and<br />

2−β 1<br />

π M = w 1 V [(1 − α)(V − p∗ − w d<br />

1 − β 1<br />

)] + w d<br />

1<br />

V [α(V − w d<br />

β 2<br />

) + (1 − α)( p∗ − w d<br />

1 − β 1<br />

− w d<br />

β 1<br />

)].<br />

From the first-order conditions, we have w ∗ = [β 2 − α(1 − β 1 )(β 2 − β 1 )]V<br />

and wd ∗ 2(αβ 1 + β 2 − αβ 2 )<br />

= β 1 β 2 V<br />

2(αβ 1 + β 2 − αβ 2 ) .<br />

Note that wd ∗ ≤ β 1(1 − β 1 )V + β 1 w ∗<br />

β 2<br />

if and only if α ≤<br />

2 − β 1 3(β 2 − β 1 ) . In addition, w∗ ≤ V if and only<br />

β 2<br />

if α ≤<br />

(1 + β 1 )(β 2 − β 1 ) . Thus, w∗ d ≤ β 1(1 − β 1 )V + β 1 w ∗<br />

implies w ∗ ≤ V . Under this strategy,<br />

2 − β 1<br />

p = [(3 − β 1)β 2 − 3α(1 − β 1 )(β 2 − β 1 )]V<br />

4[αβ 1 + β 2 − αβ 2 ]<br />

, Q = 1 − α<br />

4<br />

, Q M d = 1 + α ,<br />

4<br />

π M = [αβ 1(1 − α)(1 − β 1 ) + β 2 + β 1 β 2 − αβ 2 (2 − α)(1 − β 1 )]V<br />

8(αβ 1 + β 2 − αβ 2 )<br />

Second, under CS’-M, p ∗ = w d<br />

β 1<br />

and<br />

π M = w 1 V [(1 − α)(V − w d<br />

β 1<br />

)] + w d<br />

1<br />

V [α(V − w d<br />

β 2<br />

)].<br />

, π R = (1 − α)(1 − β 1)V<br />

16<br />

The above formula suggests that the manufacturer would like to make w as large as possible. Thus,<br />

at optimality w ∗ satisfies w d = β 1(1 − β 1 )V + β 1 w ∗<br />

. This implies that as long as Strategy GE-M is<br />

2 − β 1<br />

a feasible (<strong>in</strong>terior) solution, Strategy CS’-M is dom<strong>in</strong>ated. Substitut<strong>in</strong>g w d = β 1(1−β 1 )V +β 1 w<br />

2−β 1<br />

<strong>in</strong> π M ,<br />

we obta<strong>in</strong> from the first-order condition that w ∗ = [(2 − β 1)β 2 − α(1 − β 1 )(2β1 2 + 2β 2 − β 1 β 2 )]V<br />

2[αβ1 2 + (1 − α)(2 − β ;<br />

1)β 2 ]<br />

accord<strong>in</strong>gly,<br />

π M = [β 2 + α 2 (1 − β 1 )(4β 2 1 + β 2 − 5β 1 β 2 ) − 2α(1 − β 1 )(2β 2 1 + β 2 − 2β 1 β 2 )]V<br />

4[(2 − β 1 )β 2 + α(β 2 1 − 2β 2 + β 1 β 2 )]<br />

Third, under CS-M, p ∗ = V +w<br />

2<br />

and<br />

π M = w 1 V [(1 − α)(V − p∗ )] + w d<br />

1<br />

V [α(V − w d<br />

β 2<br />

)].<br />

From the first-order conditions, we have w ∗ = V 2<br />

and w∗ d = β 2V<br />

2 . Obviously, w∗ < wd ∗ < β 2(V +w ∗ )<br />

2<br />

.<br />

Note that β 1(V +w ∗ )<br />

2<br />

≤ wd ∗ if and only if β 2 ≥ 3 2 β 1. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, p = 3V 4 , Q = 1−α<br />

4 , QM d<br />

= α 2 ,<br />

25<br />

.<br />

.


π M = (1−α+2αβ 2)V<br />

8<br />

, and π R = (1−α)V<br />

16<br />

. F<strong>in</strong>ally, if w > V , π M = w d<br />

1<br />

V [α(V − w d<br />

β 2<br />

)].<br />

optimality w ∗ d = β 2V<br />

2 , and π M = αβ 2V<br />

4<br />

< (1 − α + 2αβ 2)V<br />

8<br />

Thus, at<br />

. It is therefore a dom<strong>in</strong>ated strategy.<br />

We can then compare the manufacturer’s pay<strong>of</strong>fs under three strategies and determ<strong>in</strong>e the<br />

optimal strategy. The algebra is tedious and the table <strong>in</strong> the proposition summarizes the equilibrium<br />

outcomes <strong>in</strong> this scenario.<br />

A.3 Only the retailer can <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> channel<br />

In the ma<strong>in</strong> text, we have discussed the consumers’ purchas<strong>in</strong>g decisions. Below, we characterize<br />

the equilibrium behaviors <strong>in</strong> two stages.<br />

A.3.1<br />

Retailer’s optimal strategy<br />

When 0 ≤ w ≤ V , the retailer’s pr<strong>of</strong>it is π R = (p − w)Q + (p d − w)Q R d ; when V ≤ w ≤ β 2V ,<br />

π R = (p d − w) 1 V [α(V − p d<br />

β 2<br />

)]. We first discuss the case 0 ≤ w ≤ V , and then consider the case<br />

V ≤ w ≤ β 2 V .<br />

Suppose that 0 ≤ w ≤ V . First, when p d ≤ β 1 p,<br />

π R = (p − w) 1 V [(1 − α)(V − p − p d<br />

1 − β 1<br />

)] + (p d − w) 1 V [α(V − p d<br />

β 2<br />

) + (1 − α)( p − p d<br />

1 − β 1<br />

− p d<br />

β 1<br />

)].<br />

From the first-order conditions, we have p ∗ = (1 − β 1){αβ 1 (β 2 − β 1 )V + [αβ 1 + (1 − α)β 2 ]w}<br />

and<br />

2[αβ 1 + (1 − α)β 2 ]<br />

p ∗ d = β 1β 2 V + [αβ 1 + (1 − α)β 2 ]w<br />

. Note that p ∗ d<br />

2[αβ 1 + (1 − α)β 2 ]<br />

≥ β 1p ∗ , and thus p d ≤ β 1 p is not an optimal<br />

strategy. Second, when β 1 p ≤ p d ≤ β 2 p,<br />

π R = (p − w) 1 V [(1 − α)(V − p)] + (p d − w) 1 V [α(V − p d<br />

β 2<br />

)].<br />

From the first-order conditions, we have p ∗ = V +w<br />

2<br />

and p ∗ d = β 2V +w<br />

2<br />

. Note that β 1 p ∗ ≤ p ∗ d ≤ β 2p ∗ .<br />

Given p ∗ and p ∗ d , we have Q = 1 V −w<br />

V<br />

[(1 − α)<br />

2<br />

] and Q R d = 1 V [α β 2V −w<br />

2β 2<br />

]. Third, when p d ≥ β 2 p,<br />

π R = (p − w) 1 V [α( p d − p<br />

β 2 − 1 − p) + (1 − α)(V − p)] + (p d − w) 1 V [α(V − p d − p<br />

β 2 − 1 )].<br />

From the first-order conditions, we have p ∗ = V +w<br />

2<br />

and p ∗ d = β 2V +w<br />

2<br />

. Note that p ∗ d ≤ β 2p ∗ , and<br />

thus p d ≥ β 2 p is not the optimal strategy.<br />

On the other hand, when V ≤ w ≤ β 2 V , the retailer’s pr<strong>of</strong>it is π R = (p d − w) 1 V [α(V − p d<br />

β 2<br />

)].<br />

From the first-order condition, we have p ∗ d = β 2V +w<br />

2<br />

and thus Q R d = 1 V [α β 2V −w<br />

2β 2<br />

].<br />

26


A.3.2<br />

Manufacturer’s optimal strategy<br />

The manufacturer has two strategies: 1) CS-R: 0 ≤ w ≤ V ; 2) EO: V ≤ w ≤ β 2 V . Next, we<br />

analyze the manufacturer’s optimal w. Under CS-R, the manufacturer’s pr<strong>of</strong>it is<br />

π M = w(Q + Q R d ) = w V<br />

From the first-order condition, we have w ∗ =<br />

[(1 − α)V<br />

− w<br />

2<br />

+ α β 2V − w<br />

2β 2<br />

].<br />

β 2 V<br />

2[α + (1 − α)β 2 ] and thus π M =<br />

β 2 V<br />

8[α+(1−α)β 2 ] .<br />

Under EO-R, the manufacturer’s pr<strong>of</strong>it is π M = w V [α β 2V −w<br />

2β 2<br />

]. From the first-order condition,<br />

we have w ∗ = β 2V<br />

2<br />

and thus π M = αβ 2V<br />

β 2 V<br />

8<br />

. Note that<br />

2[α + (1 − α)β 2 ] < β 2V<br />

. Therefore, when<br />

2<br />

β 2 V<br />

2<br />

≤ V (i.e. β 2 ≤ 2), w ∗ =<br />

w ∗ = β 2V<br />

2 . When β 2 V<br />

β 2 V<br />

If<br />

≥ αβ 2V<br />

8[α + (1 − α)β 2 ] 8<br />

β 2 V<br />

2[α + (1 − α)β 2 ] . When β 2 V<br />

2[α+(1−α)β 2 ]<br />

≥ V (i.e. α ≥<br />

2[α+(1−α)β 2 ]<br />

≤ V ≤ β 2V<br />

2<br />

(i.e. β 2 ≥ 2 and α ≤ β 2<br />

(i.e. α ≤ 1<br />

β 2 −1 ), then w∗ =<br />

2(β 2 −1)<br />

β 2<br />

2(β 2 −1) ),<br />

), there are two cases.<br />

β 2 V<br />

2[α+(1−α)β 2 ]; on the other hand, if<br />

αβ 2 V β 2 V<br />

≥<br />

(i.e. α ≥ 1<br />

8 8[α + (1 − α)β 2 ]<br />

β 2 −1<br />

), then w∗ = β 2V<br />

2<br />

. We can then compare the two<br />

strategies and the equilibrium outcomes are summarized <strong>in</strong> the table <strong>in</strong> the proposition.<br />

A.4 Both parties can <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong><br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, we consider the scenario <strong>in</strong> which both parties have the capabilities <strong>of</strong> operat<strong>in</strong>g their<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>. As the derivations are complicated, we first start with some separate cases and<br />

exam<strong>in</strong>e the manufacturer’s optimal strategies <strong>in</strong> these four different regions. Follow<strong>in</strong>g this, we<br />

then compare the manufacturer’s pay<strong>of</strong>fs across four regions to characterize the equilibrium channel<br />

structure <strong>in</strong> every <strong>in</strong>stance.<br />

A.4.1<br />

Manufacturer’s optimal pric<strong>in</strong>g and channel strategies<br />

Given the manufacturer’s strategies w and w d , we can divide our analysis <strong>in</strong>to the follow<strong>in</strong>g four<br />

cases: 1.1) 0 ≤ w ≤ V and w d ≥ β 2V +w<br />

2<br />

; 1.2) 0 ≤ w ≤ V and w ≤ w d ≤ β 2V +w<br />

2<br />

; 1.3) 0 ≤ w ≤ V<br />

and w d ≤ w, and 1.4) w > V and 0 ≤ w d ≤ β 2 V .<br />

1) 0 ≤ w ≤ V and w d ≥ β 2V +w<br />

2<br />

:<br />

When the price w d is sufficiently large (w d > β 2V +w<br />

2<br />

), the game is equivalent to the case<br />

without the manufacturer’s <strong>Internet</strong> channel from the retailer’s viewpo<strong>in</strong>t as the manufacturer’s<br />

27


<strong>Internet</strong> channel is not competitive. Thus, p ∗ = V +w<br />

2<br />

, p ∗ d = β 2V +w<br />

2<br />

, Q = 1 V −w<br />

V<br />

[(1 − α)<br />

2<br />

], and<br />

Q R d = 1 V [α β 2V −w<br />

2β 2<br />

]. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, π M = w(Q + Q R d ) = w V −w<br />

V<br />

[(1 − α)<br />

2<br />

+ α β 2V −w<br />

2β 2<br />

].<br />

2) 0 ≤ w ≤ V and w ≤ w d ≤ β 2V +w<br />

2<br />

:<br />

From the above discussions, <strong>in</strong> this case the manufacturer’s sell<strong>in</strong>g price w d sets a limit on the<br />

retailer’s sell<strong>in</strong>g price p d . In equilibrium, p ∗ d = w d, and all the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers purchase from<br />

the retailer’s <strong>Internet</strong> channel (if this were not the case, the retailer could simply lower the price<br />

p d to attract all the <strong>Internet</strong> shoppers). S<strong>in</strong>ce p ∗ d = w d, the reduction <strong>of</strong> w d mitigates the double<br />

marg<strong>in</strong>alization problem <strong>in</strong> the physical channel as well. In the sequel, w ∗ d<br />

detailed pro<strong>of</strong>.<br />

3) 0 ≤ w ≤ V and w d ≤ w :<br />

In this case, p d<br />

= w. We omit the<br />

< w is an obviously dom<strong>in</strong>ated strategy for the retailer, because all the<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> shoppers will purchase <strong>in</strong> the manufacturer’s <strong>Internet</strong> channel. In addition, p < w is also<br />

a dom<strong>in</strong>ated strategy. Thus, it is impossible to see w d ≥ β 2 p. The demand <strong>in</strong> the physical channel<br />

Q is<br />

Q =<br />

and the demand on the <strong>Internet</strong> Q M d<br />

{ 1<br />

V [(1 − α)(V − p−w d<br />

1−β 1<br />

)], if w d ≤ β 1 p<br />

1<br />

V [(1 − α)(V − p)], if β 1p ≤ w d ≤ w ,<br />

is<br />

Q M d<br />

{ 1 = V [α(V − w d<br />

β 2<br />

) + (1 − α)( p−w d<br />

1−β 1<br />

− w d<br />

β 1<br />

)], if w d ≤ β 1 p<br />

1<br />

V [α(V − w d<br />

β 2<br />

)], if β 1 p ≤ w d ≤ w<br />

.<br />

We can then exam<strong>in</strong>e possible equilibria <strong>in</strong> two cases. From the above demand functions,<br />

we shall divide our analysis <strong>in</strong>to two cases: 1) w d ≤ β 1 w and 2) β 1 w ≤ w d ≤ w because the<br />

manufacturer’s pric<strong>in</strong>g strategy will <strong>in</strong>fluence the retailer’s counteraction. The algebra is tedious;<br />

by and large, we compare across different scenarios to determ<strong>in</strong>e their optimal strategies. The table<br />

below summarizes π M , π R and feasibility conditions <strong>of</strong> the three strategies when β 1 w ≤ w d ≤ w; a<br />

similar table can be constructed for w d ≤ β 1 w.<br />

28


Strategy π M and π R Feasibility Conditions<br />

GE-M<br />

CS’-M π M =<br />

CS”-M<br />

π M = [αβ 1(1−α)(1−β 1 )+β 2 +β 1 β 2 −αβ 2 (2−α)(1−β 1 )]V<br />

8(αβ 1 +β 2 −αβ 2 )<br />

π R = (1−α)(1−β 1)V<br />

⎧<br />

⎪⎨<br />

⎪⎩<br />

16<br />

[β 2 + α 2 (1 − β 1 )(4β 2 1 + β 2 − 5β 1 β 2 )<br />

−2α(1 − β 1 )(2β 2 1 + β 2 − 2β 1 β 2 )]V<br />

4[(2−β 1 )β 2 +α(β 2 1 −2β 2+β 1 β 2 )]<br />

π R = (1−α)(1−β 1)[β 2 +α(2β 2 1 −β 2−β 1 β 2 )]V<br />

4[(2−β 1 )β 2 +α(β 2 1 −2β 2+β 1 β 2 )] 2<br />

π M =<br />

(1+α)2 β 2 V<br />

8(2α+β 2 −αβ 2 ) − f<br />

π R = (1−α)(4α+β 2−3αβ 2 ) 2 V<br />

16(2α+β 2 −αβ 2 )<br />

− f<br />

⎫<br />

⎪⎬<br />

⎪⎭<br />

− f<br />

α ≤<br />

α ≥<br />

β 2<br />

3(β 2 −β 1 )<br />

β 2<br />

3(β 2 −β 1 )<br />

(β 2 + β 1 β 2 − 2β 2 1 )α ≤ β 2<br />

(2β 2 + β 1 β 2 − 4β 1 )α ≥<br />

(3β 1 − 2)β 2<br />

(3β 2 − 4)α ≤ β 2<br />

4) w > V and 0 ≤ w d ≤ β 2 V<br />

If w > V , π M = w d<br />

1<br />

V [α(V − w d<br />

β 2<br />

)]. Thus, w ∗ d = β 2V<br />

2 , and then π M = αβ 2V<br />

4<br />

. It is the strategy<br />

EO-M.<br />

5) Comparison across the first four regions:<br />

From the above analysis, we f<strong>in</strong>d that when α ≤<br />

is GE-M, CS”-M, or EO-M. When α ≥<br />

β 2<br />

3(β 2 −β 1 )<br />

β 2<br />

3(β 2 −β 1 ), the manufacturer’s optimal strategy<br />

, his optimal strategy lies between CS’-M, CS”-M,<br />

or EO-M. Thus, we can simply compare the pay<strong>of</strong>fs across the regions to obta<strong>in</strong> the manufacturer’s<br />

optimal strategy. We omit the tedious calculations here.<br />

A.4.2<br />

Equilibrium channel structure<br />

We now consider the equilibrium channel structure.<br />

For ease <strong>of</strong> exposition, we use N and I to<br />

represent their channel choices, where N corresponds to “no <strong>Internet</strong> channel,” and I corresponds<br />

to “<strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> channel.” We further use (I,N) to represent the subgame <strong>in</strong> which the<br />

manufacturer <strong>in</strong>troduces his <strong>Internet</strong> channel (the first argument), and the retailer decides not to<br />

do so (the second argument). Likewise, we use (I,I), (N,I), and (N,N) to <strong>in</strong>dicate other channel<br />

structures. Recall that f denotes the manufacturer’s operat<strong>in</strong>g cost for the <strong>Internet</strong> channel, where<br />

0 < f < αβ 2V<br />

8<br />

. The retailer’s operat<strong>in</strong>g cost is normalized to zero.<br />

We first show that (N,N) is not an equilibrium. Given that the manufacturer does not <strong>in</strong>troduce<br />

the <strong>Internet</strong> channel, if the retailer also abandons the <strong>Internet</strong> channel, she obta<strong>in</strong>s the pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

π R = V 16 . If she <strong>in</strong>troduces her <strong>Internet</strong> channel, π R = [β 2 + 4α(1 − α)(β 2 − 1) 2 ]V<br />

if α ≤ 1<br />

16[α + (1 − α)β 2 ]<br />

β 2 −1 , and<br />

π R = αβ 2V<br />

16<br />

if α ≥ 1<br />

β 2 −1 . Compar<strong>in</strong>g the pr<strong>of</strong>its, we obta<strong>in</strong> that [β 2+4α(1−α)(β 2 −1) 2 ]V<br />

16[α+(1−α)β 2 ]<br />

≥ V 16 implies<br />

29


β 2 +4(1−α)(β 2 −1) 2 ≥ 1, which always holds after rout<strong>in</strong>e algebra. In addition, αβ 2V<br />

16<br />

≥ V 16 implies<br />

αβ 2 ≥ 1, which is satisfied when α ≥ 1<br />

β 2 −1<br />

. Thus, (N,N) is never an equilibrium.<br />

Next, we prove that (I,I) is not an equilibrium either. Given that the manufacturer <strong>in</strong>troduces<br />

the <strong>Internet</strong> channel, if the retailer also does so, the possible equilibrium is GE-M, CS”-<br />

M, CS”-M or EO-M. First, if GE-M is the equilibrium strategy, then the retailer obta<strong>in</strong>s the<br />

pay<strong>of</strong>f π R = (1−α)(1−β 1)V<br />

16<br />

. Nevertheless, if she abandons her <strong>Internet</strong> channel, her pay<strong>of</strong>f becomes<br />

either π R = (1−α)(1−β 1)V<br />

16<br />

(GE-M) or π R = (1−α)V<br />

16<br />

(CS-M). In both cases, the retailer has<br />

an <strong>in</strong>centive to deviate. Second, if the equilibrium strategy is CS’-M, then the retailer obta<strong>in</strong>s<br />

π R = (1 − α)(1 − β 1)[β 2 + α(2β1 2 − β 2 − β 1 β 2 )]V<br />

4[(2 − β 1 )β 2 + α(β1 2 − 2β 2 + β 1 β 2 )] 2 . Abandon<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>Internet</strong> channel, she obta<strong>in</strong>s<br />

either π R = (1 − α)(1 − β 1)[β 2 + α(2β1 2 − β 2 − β 1 β 2 )]V<br />

4[(2 − β 1 )β 2 + α(β1 2 − 2β 2 + β 1 β 2 )] 2 (CS’-M) or π R = (1−α)V<br />

16<br />

(CS-M), which<br />

dom<strong>in</strong>ates CS’-M.<br />

Third, if the equilibrium strategy is CS”-M (a necessary condition is α(2β 2 − 3) ≤ 1), then<br />

the retailer’s pay<strong>of</strong>f is π R = (1 − α)(4α + β 2 − 3αβ 2 ) 2 V<br />

. If <strong>in</strong>stead the retailer abandons the<br />

16(2α + β 2 − αβ 2 )<br />

<strong>Internet</strong> channel, the equilibrium must be CS-M (because the manufacturer obta<strong>in</strong>s a strictly<br />

higher pay<strong>of</strong>f under CS-M than under CS”-M). In such a scenario, the retailer’s pay<strong>of</strong>f is π R =<br />

(1−α)V (1 − α)V<br />

16<br />

. S<strong>in</strong>ce − (1 − α)(4α + β 2 − 3αβ 2 ) 2 V<br />

= α(1 − α)(β 2 − 1)(3α + β 2 − 2αβ 2 )V<br />

16 16(2α + β 2 − αβ 2 )<br />

4(2α + β 2 − αβ 2 ) 2 > 0<br />

(as α(2β 2 − 3) ≤ 1 implies α(2β 2 − 3) ≤ β 2 ), we identify a pr<strong>of</strong>itable deviation for the retailer.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, if EO-M is the equilibrium, the retailer obta<strong>in</strong>s a null pay<strong>of</strong>f π R = 0. This is certa<strong>in</strong>ly<br />

suboptimal because by abandon<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>Internet</strong> channel she obta<strong>in</strong>s at least some positive pay<strong>of</strong>f.<br />

In sum, (I,I) can never be susta<strong>in</strong>ed as an equilibrium. The table <strong>in</strong> the proposition summarizes<br />

the equilibrium channel structures <strong>in</strong> different scenarios.<br />

B<br />

Retailer competition<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ce each <strong>supply</strong> cha<strong>in</strong> party can decide whether to <strong>in</strong>troduce the <strong>Internet</strong> channel, there are<br />

eight possible subgames. In the first stage, we exam<strong>in</strong>e the equilibrium pric<strong>in</strong>g strategies <strong>in</strong> each<br />

subgame. In the second stage, we then exam<strong>in</strong>e the equilibrium channel structure.<br />

B.1 Equilibrium pric<strong>in</strong>g strategies<br />

We aga<strong>in</strong> adopt the same notation N and I to represent their channel choices. We further use<br />

(I,N,I) to represent the subgame <strong>in</strong> which the manufacturer <strong>in</strong>troduces his <strong>Internet</strong> channel (the<br />

30


first argument), retailer 1 decides not to do so (N), and retailer 2 <strong>in</strong>troduces her <strong>Internet</strong> channel<br />

as well (the last argument). Likewise, we use the triples to <strong>in</strong>dicate other channel structures. It is<br />

readily observable that (N,I,N) and (N,N,I) are symmetric, and (I,I,N) and (I,N,I) are symmetric.<br />

Thus, <strong>in</strong> the sequel we only discuss the former two cases, which leaves us with six subgames <strong>in</strong><br />

total. Note that <strong>in</strong> evaluat<strong>in</strong>g the equilibrium pric<strong>in</strong>g strategies, the manufacturer’s operat<strong>in</strong>g cost<br />

has been sunk and thus does not factor <strong>in</strong>to these subgame derivations.<br />

B.1.1<br />

Scenario (N,N,N)<br />

In the absence <strong>of</strong> <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong>, the retailers compete head-to-head <strong>in</strong> their physical <strong>channels</strong>.<br />

Thus, given the manufacturer’s wholesale price w, the equilibrium sell<strong>in</strong>g prices are p 1 = p 2 = w.<br />

In accordance, a consumer buys the product if and only if v − w ≥ 0.<br />

This gives rise to the<br />

manufacturer’s expected pr<strong>of</strong>it π M = w 1 V (V −w). From the first-order conditions, we have w∗ = V 2<br />

and Q ∗ = 1 2 . Therefore, π M = V 4 . To summarize, <strong>in</strong> this subgame, w∗ = p ∗ 1 = p∗ 2 = V 2 , Q∗ = 1 2 ,<br />

π M = V 4 and π R1 = π R2 = 0.<br />

B.1.2<br />

Scenario (N,I,N)<br />

Now suppose that only retailer 1 <strong>in</strong>troduces her <strong>Internet</strong> channel. We aga<strong>in</strong> obta<strong>in</strong> that <strong>in</strong> the<br />

physical <strong>channels</strong> the equilibrium sell<strong>in</strong>g prices are p 1 = p 2 = w. To exam<strong>in</strong>e the manufacturer’s<br />

optimal wholesale price, we divide our analysis <strong>in</strong>to two cases: 1) 0 ≤ w ≤ V and 2) V < w ≤ β 2 V .<br />

Case A. 0 ≤ w ≤ V :<br />

Obviously, p 1d < w is a dom<strong>in</strong>ated strategy for retailer 1 as it generates no sales. Thus, we<br />

ignore the case p 1d ≤ β 1 w. The demand <strong>in</strong> the physical channel Q is<br />

{ 1<br />

V<br />

Q =<br />

[(1 − α)(V − w)], if w ≤ p 1d ≤ β 2 w<br />

1<br />

V [α( p 1d−w<br />

β 2 −1 − w) + (1 − α)(V − w)], if β 2w ≤ p 1d ≤ β 2 V ,<br />

and the demand on the <strong>Internet</strong> Q d is<br />

{ 1<br />

V<br />

Q d =<br />

[α(V − p 1d<br />

β 2<br />

)], if w ≤ p 1d ≤ β 2 w<br />

1<br />

V [α(V − p 1d−w<br />

β 2 −1 )], if β 2w ≤ p 1d ≤ β 2 V .<br />

Based on the above demands, let us consider the optimal pric<strong>in</strong>g strategy p ∗ 1d<br />

First, when w ≤ p 1d ≤ β 2 w,<br />

for retailer 1.<br />

π R1 = (p 1d − w)Q d = (p 1d − w) 1 V [α(V − p 1d<br />

β 2<br />

)].<br />

31


Apply<strong>in</strong>g the first-order conditions, we have p ∗ 1d = β 2V + w<br />

. Note that p ∗ 1d<br />

≥ w always holds, and<br />

2<br />

p ∗ 1d ≤ β 2w if and only if w ≥ . Thus, we obta<strong>in</strong> the equilibrium pay<strong>of</strong>fs:<br />

β 2V<br />

2β 2 −1<br />

π R1 = α(β 2V − w) 2<br />

, and π M = w 1 4β 2 V<br />

V [(1 − α)(V − w) + α(V − β 2V + w<br />

)].<br />

2β 2<br />

We can do similar calculations for the case p 1d ≥ β 2 w.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, we can characterize the manufacturer’s<br />

optimal wholesale price w ∗ based on the above derivations.<br />

here.<br />

Case B. V < w ≤ β 2 V<br />

The algebra is omitted<br />

In this case no consumer prefers to purchase <strong>in</strong> the physical channel because the wholesale price<br />

and subsequently the sell<strong>in</strong>g prices are too high. Thus, π R1 = (p 1d −w)Q d = (p 1d −w) 1 V [α(V − p 1d<br />

β 2<br />

)].<br />

Follow<strong>in</strong>g the first-order conditions, we have p ∗ 1d = β 2V +w<br />

2<br />

. Thus, π M = w 1 V [α(V − β 2V +w<br />

2β 2<br />

)]. This<br />

gives rise to w ∗ = β 2V<br />

2 . Note that w∗ > V if and only if β 2 > 2, <strong>in</strong> which case π M = αβ 2V<br />

8<br />

.<br />

We can then determ<strong>in</strong>e the manufacturer’s optimal wholesale price strategy by compar<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

two cases.<br />

B.1.3<br />

Other scenarios and summary<br />

Follow<strong>in</strong>g the same procedure, we can f<strong>in</strong>d the equilibria <strong>in</strong> the other four subgames (N,I,I), (I,N,N),<br />

(I,I,N) and (I,I,I). We summarize the manufacturer, retailer 1 and retailer 2’s equilibrium pr<strong>of</strong>its<br />

<strong>in</strong> the table below.<br />

Subgame π M π R1 π R2<br />

(N,I,I)<br />

(I,N,N)<br />

(I,I,N)<br />

(I,I,I)<br />

αβ 2 V<br />

4<br />

0 0<br />

(1−α+αβ 2 )V<br />

αβ 2 V<br />

4<br />

0 0<br />

4<br />

− f 0 0<br />

β 2 V<br />

4(α+β 2 −αβ 2 ) − f 0 0<br />

B.2 Equilibrium channel structures<br />

We have paved the way to characterize all the equilibria <strong>in</strong> every subgame. Now we can exam<strong>in</strong>e the<br />

channel strategies <strong>of</strong> the manufacturer and the retailers. First, neither <strong>of</strong> (N,N,N) and (I,N,N) will<br />

be an equilibrium. This is because given the strategies <strong>of</strong> the manufacturer and retailer 2, retailer<br />

1 obta<strong>in</strong>s a null pay<strong>of</strong>f. However, she always benefits from <strong><strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g</strong> her <strong>Internet</strong> channel and<br />

32


claims a strictly positive pay<strong>of</strong>f. Second, (I,I,I) is never an equilibrium. To see this, let us take the<br />

retailers’ strategies as given. When α ≤ 1<br />

he obta<strong>in</strong>s the pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

β 2 V<br />

4(α+β 2 −αβ 2 )<br />

β 2 V<br />

4(α+β 2 −αβ 2 )<br />

β 2 −1<br />

, if the manufacturer <strong>in</strong>troduces his <strong>Internet</strong> channel,<br />

− f. On the other hand, if he abandons it, his pr<strong>of</strong>it becomes<br />

as he saves the operat<strong>in</strong>g cost but obta<strong>in</strong>s the same gross revenue. When α ≥<br />

1<br />

β 2 −1 ,<br />

if the manufacturer <strong>in</strong>troduces the <strong>Internet</strong> channel, his pr<strong>of</strong>it is αβ 2V<br />

4<br />

− f; aga<strong>in</strong>, he can save his<br />

cost by abandon<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>Internet</strong> channel (the pr<strong>of</strong>it is then αβ 2V<br />

4<br />

).<br />

Third, (N,I,I) is always an equilibrium. To verify this, first observe that given the retailers’<br />

strategies, the manufacturer has no <strong>in</strong>centive to <strong>in</strong>troduce his own <strong>Internet</strong> channel because he<br />

obta<strong>in</strong>s exactly the same gross revenue. Given that the manufacturer does not <strong>in</strong>troduce his <strong>Internet</strong><br />

channel but retailer 2 does, retailer 1’s pr<strong>of</strong>it is zero regardless <strong>of</strong> whether he <strong>in</strong>troduces his <strong>Internet</strong><br />

channel. Thus, he has no <strong>in</strong>centive to deviate. Likewise, retailer 2 does not want to deviate by<br />

symmetry.<br />

The last two cases are possible equilibria but also require some feasibility conditions.<br />

consider first (N,I,N). Given the equilibrium strategies <strong>of</strong> the manufacturer and retailer 2, if retailer<br />

1 abandons her <strong>Internet</strong> channel, she obta<strong>in</strong>s a null pay<strong>of</strong>f. Thus, she has no <strong>in</strong>centive to deviate.<br />

Given the equilibrium strategies <strong>of</strong> the manufacturer and retailer 1, retailer 2 cannot obta<strong>in</strong> a<br />

positive pay<strong>of</strong>f regardless <strong>of</strong> whether she <strong>in</strong>troduces her <strong>Internet</strong> channel.<br />

We<br />

This elim<strong>in</strong>ates any<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>itable deviation as well. F<strong>in</strong>ally, given the retailers’ equilibrium strategies, the manufacturer’s<br />

pay<strong>of</strong>f depends on the consumer composition.<br />

In the last scenario, (I,I,N) can be susta<strong>in</strong>ed as an equilibrium under some conditions characterized<br />

below. Given the equilibrium strategies <strong>of</strong> the manufacturer and retailer 2, if retailer<br />

1 abandons her <strong>Internet</strong> channel, she obta<strong>in</strong>s a null pay<strong>of</strong>f and thus it is not a pr<strong>of</strong>itable deviation.<br />

Given the equilibrium strategies <strong>of</strong> the manufacturer and retailer 1, retailer 2 is <strong>in</strong>different<br />

between <strong><strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g</strong> her <strong>Internet</strong> channel or not. To elim<strong>in</strong>ate any possible pr<strong>of</strong>itable deviation<br />

for the manufacturer, we need the follow<strong>in</strong>g conditions: (1) when α ≤ 1<br />

β 2 −1 , f ≤ α(β 2−1)V<br />

4(α+β 2 −αβ 2 ) ; (2)<br />

1<br />

when<br />

β 2 −1 ≤ a ≤ 2 β 2<br />

, f ≤ (αβ 2−1)V<br />

4<br />

; (3) when 2 β 2<br />

≤ α ≤ 2β 2<br />

3β 2 −2 , f ≤ [4(1−α)(αβ 2−1)+α 2 ]V<br />

8(α+2β 2 −2αβ 2 )<br />

; (4) when<br />

α ≥ 2β 2<br />

3β 2 −2 , f ≤ αβ 2V<br />

8<br />

.<br />

C<br />

Sell<strong>in</strong>g through an e-tailer<br />

In this section, we consider the scenario where<strong>in</strong> the manufacturer sells through an onl<strong>in</strong>e retailer<br />

(e-tailer). We shall discuss two possible cases, depend<strong>in</strong>g on whether the retailer can <strong>in</strong>troduce her<br />

own <strong>Internet</strong> channel.<br />

33


C.1 The retailer can only sell through the physical channel<br />

Given 0 ≤ p ≤ V and 0 ≤ p d ≤ β 2 V , the demand <strong>in</strong> the physical channel Q is<br />

⎧<br />

1<br />

⎪⎨ V [(1 − α)(V − p−p d<br />

1−β 1<br />

)], if p d ≤ β 1 p<br />

Q =<br />

1<br />

V<br />

⎪⎩<br />

[(1 − α)(V − p)], if β 1p ≤ p d ≤ β 2 p ,<br />

1<br />

V [α( p d−p<br />

β 2 −1 − p) + (1 − α)(V − p)], if p d ≥ β 2 p<br />

and the demand on the <strong>Internet</strong> Q d is<br />

⎧<br />

1<br />

⎪⎨ V [α(V − p d<br />

β 2<br />

) + (1 − α)( p−p d<br />

1−β 1<br />

− p d<br />

β 1<br />

)], if p d ≤ β 1 p<br />

Q d =<br />

1<br />

V<br />

⎪⎩<br />

[α(V − p d<br />

β 2<br />

)], if β 1 p ≤ p d ≤ β 2 p<br />

1<br />

V [α(V − p d−p<br />

β 2 −1 )], if p d ≥ β 2 p<br />

By backward <strong>in</strong>duction, we shall start with the subgame <strong>in</strong> which the retailer and e-tailer compete<br />

<strong>in</strong> prices; afterwards, we return to the manufacturer’s pric<strong>in</strong>g decisions.<br />

.<br />

C.1.1<br />

Retailer’s and e-tailer’s strategies<br />

Now we consider the e-tailer’s strategy. Let p ∗ and p ∗ d<br />

denote the equilibrium sell<strong>in</strong>g prices. There<br />

are five possible cases: i) p ∗ d < β 1p ∗ , ii) β 1 p ∗ < p ∗ d < β 2p ∗ , iii) p ∗ d > β 2p ∗ , iv) p ∗ d = β 1p ∗ , and v)<br />

p ∗ d = β 2p ∗ .<br />

In case i) p ∗ d < β 1p ∗ , π R = (p − w) 1 V [(1 − α)(V − p−p d<br />

1−β 1<br />

)]. Follow<strong>in</strong>g the first-order condition, we<br />

obta<strong>in</strong> the optimal price p ∗ = (1−β 1)V +w+p d<br />

2<br />

. In addition, π A = (p d −w d ) 1 V [α(V − p d<br />

β 2<br />

)+(1−α)( p−p d<br />

1−β 1<br />

−<br />

p d<br />

β 1<br />

)]. The first-order condition suggests that p ∗ d = αβ 1β 2 (1−β 1 )V +[αβ 1 (1−β 1 )+(1−α)β 2 ]w d +(1−α)β 1 β 2 p<br />

2[αβ 1 (1−β 1 )+(1−α)β 2 ]<br />

.<br />

Solv<strong>in</strong>g these equations jo<strong>in</strong>tly, we f<strong>in</strong>d that<br />

p ∗ = (1 − β 1)V + w<br />

2<br />

+ (1 + α)(1 − β 1)β 1 β 2 V + (1 − α)β 1 β 2 w + 2[αβ 1 (1 − β 1 ) + (1 − α)β 2 ]w d<br />

(1) ,<br />

8αβ 1 (1 − β 1 ) + 2(1 − α)(4 − β 1 )β 2<br />

p ∗ d = (1 + α)(1 − β 1)β 1 β 2 V + (1 − α)β 1 β 2 w + 2[αβ 1 (1 − β 1 ) + (1 − α)β 2 ]w d<br />

4αβ 1 (1 − β 1 ) + (1 − α)(4 − β 1 )β 2<br />

.<br />

p ∗ d < β 1p ∗ implies w > β 1(1−β 1 )[αβ 2 (3−β 1 )−2αβ 1 (1−β 1 )−β 2 ]V +[αβ 1 (1−β 1 )(2−β 1 )+(1−α)(2−β 1 )β 2 ]w d<br />

2αβ 2 1 (1−β 1)+(1−α)β 1 β 2<br />

. Likewise,<br />

we can also work out the other four cases. The details are omitted s<strong>in</strong>ce they follow from<br />

straightforward algebra.<br />

C.1.2<br />

Manufacturer’s strategies<br />

Now we proceed to exam<strong>in</strong>e the manufacturer’s strategies. The five cases lead to different optimal<br />

sell<strong>in</strong>g prices and subsequently different expressions <strong>of</strong> the manufacturer’s pay<strong>of</strong>fs. For example,<br />

34


when p ∗ d < β 1p ∗ ,<br />

π M = w 1 V [(1 − α)(V − p∗ − p ∗ d<br />

1 − β 1<br />

)] + w d<br />

1<br />

V [α(V − p∗ d<br />

β 2<br />

) + (1 − α)( p∗ − p ∗ d<br />

1 − β 1<br />

− p∗ d<br />

β 1<br />

)],<br />

where p ∗ and p ∗ d are given <strong>in</strong> (1). We then apply the first-order condition and obta<strong>in</strong> w∗ =<br />

[β 2 −α(1−β 1 )(β 2 −β 1 )]V<br />

2(αβ 1 +β 2 −αβ 2 )<br />

and wd ∗ = β 1 β 2 V<br />

2(αβ 1 +β 2 −αβ 2 ). In this case, the manufacturer’s pr<strong>of</strong>it is πIE<br />

M<br />

(<strong>Internet</strong><br />

encroachment). The other cases are analyzed similarly.<br />

C.2 Both the manufacturer and the retailer can <strong>in</strong>troduce <strong>Internet</strong> <strong>channels</strong><br />

We aga<strong>in</strong> use backward <strong>in</strong>duction to characterize the equilibrium. We shall dist<strong>in</strong>guish between<br />

the onl<strong>in</strong>e sell<strong>in</strong>g prices between the retailer (p R d ) and the e-tailer (pE d ). When pR d < pE d<br />

, the e-tailer<br />

has no sales; when p E d<br />

< pR d<br />

, the retailer earns noth<strong>in</strong>g from her <strong>Internet</strong> channel. Therefore, if<br />

w < w d , <strong>in</strong> equilibrium pd<br />

R∗ ≤ p E∗<br />

d<br />

= w d , and the e-tailer gets no sales. This is equivalent to the<br />

case when the manufacturer owns his <strong>Internet</strong> channel <strong>in</strong> our basic framework. Recall that we have<br />

shown that when w < w d , the manufacturer’s pay<strong>of</strong>f is decreas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> w d . Thus, <strong>in</strong> what follows, we<br />

can simply focus on the case w d ≤ w.<br />

Moreover, when w d ≤ w, <strong>in</strong> equilibrium the retailer gets no sales <strong>in</strong> her <strong>Internet</strong> channel, and<br />

p E∗<br />

d<br />

≤ w. If this is violated (i.e., p E∗<br />

d<br />

consumers that purchase from the e-tailer.<br />

> w), the retailer can always decrease p d to capture the<br />

Note that p E∗<br />

d<br />

< w is satisfied only under strategy<br />

GE-M <strong>in</strong> equilibrium. Therefore, if other equilibria can be susta<strong>in</strong>ed, it must be that p E∗<br />

d<br />

= w, <strong>in</strong><br />

which case the value <strong>of</strong> w d does not <strong>in</strong>fluence the e-tailer’s sales. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, the manufacturer<br />

will <strong>in</strong>crease the wholesale price w d as much as possible, lead<strong>in</strong>g to wd ∗ = w <strong>in</strong> equilibrium.<br />

We can then exam<strong>in</strong>e the manufacturer’s pay<strong>of</strong>f given that w = w d .<br />

For example, when<br />

w ≥ V , the <strong>in</strong>duced sell<strong>in</strong>g prices are p R d = pE d<br />

= w. The correspond<strong>in</strong>g manufacturer’s pay<strong>of</strong>f is<br />

π M = w[ 1 V α(V − w β 2<br />

)]. Apply<strong>in</strong>g the first-order condition, we have w ∗ = β 2V<br />

2<br />

and thus π M = αβ 2V<br />

4<br />

.<br />

Note that w ∗ > V if and only β 2 > 2. This strategy is labeled as strategy EO. When w ≤ V , the<br />

<strong>in</strong>duced sell<strong>in</strong>g prices become p R d = pE d<br />

= w, and there are several subcases to discuss. We can then<br />

derive the optimal wholesale prices <strong>in</strong> each subcase and then compare the manufacturer’s pay<strong>of</strong>fs<br />

across scenarios. The calculations are rout<strong>in</strong>e and tedious; thus, we omit the details and simply<br />

summarize the results <strong>in</strong> the proposition.<br />

35

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!