28.11.2014 Views

Midterm exam with suggested answers

Midterm exam with suggested answers

Midterm exam with suggested answers

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Economic Development 570: <strong>Midterm</strong> Exam<br />

Professor Tybout<br />

October 21, 2003<br />

Please put your ID number on each page you turn in, and number you pages consecutively.<br />

(For <strong>exam</strong>ple, if you turn in 6 pages, number them “1 of 6,” “2 of 6,” et cetera.) Do not put<br />

your name anywhere on the <strong>exam</strong>.<br />

You must answer both questions in part I, and one of the two questions in part II. All<br />

questions will receive equal weight. No extra credit will be awarded for answering all both<br />

questions in part II.<br />

Good luck!


Part I: Answer both of the following two questions<br />

1) (25 minutes) We have studied four models of industrialization/modernization that explain<br />

why multiple equilibria are possible, and why countries can get stuck in “low level traps:”<br />

Kevin Murphy, Andrei Schiefer and Robert Vishny (MSV): “Industrialization and the Big<br />

Push,”<br />

Paul Krugman (K): “History versus Expectations,”<br />

Paul Krugman and Anthony Venables (KV): “Globalization and the Inequality of<br />

Nations,”<br />

Dani Rodrik (R): “Coordination Failures and Government Policy: A Model <strong>with</strong><br />

Applications to East Asia and Eastern Europe”<br />

a) (20 points) Each of these models involves strategic complementarities. That is, when<br />

many agents are pursuing a given activity, the returns to pursuing that activity are<br />

increased for other agents. Explain what form the strategic complementarities take in<br />

each model mentioned above, and why they help to establish the possibility of<br />

multiple equilibria.<br />

In MSV, the strategic complementarities derive from the fact that each modern<br />

producer is more profitable when there are other modern producers around. This is<br />

because modern producers, when operating on a large scale, generate more income<br />

for their employees, and thus generate more demand for output of each good. Multiple<br />

equilibria are possible because, when no other modern sector producers are present,<br />

no one has an incentive set up a modern facility⎯demand won’t be large enough to<br />

make it more efficient than cottage production. On the other hand, if all of the other<br />

producers are modern, there is sufficient demand for each product to make modern<br />

production more profitable than cottage production.<br />

In K, the wage rate depends positively on the fraction of the labor force in the modern<br />

sector, but the strategic complementarities aren’t spelled out in detail. This<br />

specification implies external economies at the sector level, due perhaps to<br />

agglomeration economies, richer menus of intermediate goods (as in R), or the<br />

sharing of specialized knowledge. Multiple transition paths are possible because one’s<br />

beliefs about the behavior of other suppliers of factors influence one’s own behavior.<br />

More specifically, if one expects everyone else to move toward modern sector<br />

production, one is inclined to do so as well. However, unlike in MSV, the scope for<br />

multiple equilibria hinges upon the importance of adjustment costs, when create an<br />

incentive to move slowly.<br />

In KV, the strategic complementarities come from the fact that the location of other<br />

producers determines the payoff to one’s own firm at each possible location. This is<br />

because being close to other firms and their workers increases their demand for your


product (transportation is costs). On the other hand, concentration of production in a<br />

limited geographic area drives up the cost of employees. When transport costs are<br />

moderate, multiple equilibria are possible⎯one <strong>with</strong> manufacturing production<br />

consolidated in a single region and <strong>with</strong> manufacturing production spread evenly<br />

across all regions. In the former case, <strong>with</strong> consolidated production, the neglected<br />

region has no demand for manufactured inputs and its workers have little income, so it<br />

is a relatively unattractive place to locate. In the latter case, a movement toward<br />

consolidation would generate more local demand for the marginal firm, but the gains<br />

from this would be more than offset by the loss in demand due to extra transport costs<br />

when servicing customers abroad.<br />

In R, strategic complementarities result from the fact that the high-tech sector uses<br />

non-traded intermediate inputs, and the larger the menu of these intermediate inputs,<br />

the more efficiently it produces. There are scale economies in intermediate goods<br />

production, so the more demand there is for intermediate inputs, the larger the<br />

available menu of these goods. Hence when few high-tech producers are active, the<br />

menu of goods is small, and the return to high-tech production is low, so the economy<br />

tends toward low-tech production. On the other hand, when many high-tech producers<br />

are active, there are many intermediate goods available and the return to high-tech<br />

production is high, so the economy gravitates toward high-tech production.<br />

b) (13 points) Suppose a country is stuck in a low-level trap, and its economic minister<br />

asks you how to escape. Are there policies that would tend to push the country out of<br />

low-level equilibrium, regardless of which model applies? Are there policies that<br />

would work only under the assumptions of some of the models?<br />

Increased demand for the high-tech/modern good will generally tend to push an<br />

economy toward that type of production. In each context this might take the form of a<br />

subsidy, or at least a guaranteed minimum profit rate (which wouldn’t actually cost<br />

the government money if it successfully moved the economy to a modern equilibrium).<br />

Some policy implications are specific to the model, however. For <strong>exam</strong>ple, if transport<br />

costs are small, simply opening the MSV model to trade would de-link modern sector<br />

profitability from size of the modern sector. In the context of K, subsidies to workers<br />

for retraining might reduce the relative importance of history, and combined <strong>with</strong><br />

guaranteed minimum earnings in the modern sector, might bump the economy to a<br />

modern sector equilibrium. In KV, trade protection would force the emergence of<br />

domestic manufacturing; it is possible that after accomplishing this the economy<br />

would become a global manufacturing sector, or at least avoid specializing in<br />

agriculture, even if the protection is subsequently removed. Finally, in the context of<br />

the R model, subsidies to capital formation or the removal of barriers to international<br />

capital mobility may reduce the wage-rental ratio sufficiently that high-tech equilibria<br />

dominate. Minimum wages might even accomplish the same thing.


2) (25 minutes) The per capita income of Malsuerte has remained close to subsistence for<br />

the past 50 years. The Malsuertian government is convinced that the problem is a poor<br />

schooling system, so it has decided to deliver heavily subsidized primary and secondary<br />

education to all school-age children.<br />

a) (18 points) Drawing on the models of Robert Lucas (“On the Mechanics of Economic<br />

Development”), and Gary Becker, Kevin Murphy and Robert Tamura (“Human<br />

Capital, Fertility and Economic Growth”), carefully explain why this policy might lead<br />

to higher per capita income growth.<br />

In the Lucas model, there are external returns to human capital, so <strong>with</strong>out subsidies,<br />

too little gets produced in the market equilibrium. Further, the rate of growth in total<br />

factor productivity depends upon the rate of human capital accumulation, so when<br />

agents react to subsidized education by investing more in secondary education, the<br />

rates of productivity and output growth should increase. Of course, this presumes that<br />

the Lucas representation of human capital accumulation, which presumes that the<br />

growth rate in human capital is proportional to the faction of the time individuals<br />

spend schooling, is correct.<br />

In the BMT model, parents <strong>with</strong> low education levels maximize their utility by having<br />

large numbers of uneducated children. This is because (1) they are not very efficient at<br />

teaching their children, and (2) they are earning low wages, so the time costs of child<br />

rearing are relatively low. A subsidy to education may shift the balance in favor of<br />

small numbers of educated children. Further, it may result in steady state growth if the<br />

time costs of having children are sufficiently high, parents are relatively productive at<br />

endowing their children <strong>with</strong> education (given their own human capital level), and/or<br />

the marginal utility parents derive from additional children falls rapidly <strong>with</strong> n.<br />

b) (15 points) Suppose the Malsuertian economy is actually stuck in a low level trap of<br />

the type described by Dani Rodrik (“Coordination Failures and Government Policy: A<br />

Model <strong>with</strong> Applications to East Asia and Eastern Europe”). Will adding to the human<br />

capital stock help, hurt, or do nothing? Carefully explain. You may find it useful to<br />

draw a graph.<br />

This policy shock can be analyzed using the graph below.


w<br />

θ ( w,<br />

r)<br />

= 1<br />

( r , wλ(<br />

h)<br />

c(<br />

z)<br />

) π<br />

φ =<br />

r<br />

Here the function θ ( w,<br />

r)<br />

shows the cost of producing one unit of low-tech output<br />

when wages and rental rates are w and r, respectively. Similarly, the function<br />

⎛<br />

−1<br />

⎞<br />

⎜<br />

−1<br />

⎟<br />

φ<br />

σ<br />

⎜r , wλ(<br />

h)<br />

c(<br />

z)<br />

n ⎟ gives the cost of producing one unit of high-tech output at these<br />

⎝<br />

⎠<br />

factor prices when the human capital stock is h and the number of (non-traded)<br />

intermediate varieties produced domestically is n. In equilibrium, if only one type of<br />

good is produced and factor markets clear, the slope of that good’s isocost contour<br />

must match the capital labor ratio, which is depicted as a negatively sloped line<br />

segment. If the economy specializes in one good, it will choose the good that generates<br />

the larger factor payments. The outer hull of the two unit cost functions shows which<br />

product this will be and the associated factor prices, when the prices of low-tech and<br />

high-tech goods are 1 and π , respectively, and the capital-labor ratio is given by the<br />

negatively sloped line segments. Low-tech equilibria are sustainable if specialization<br />

in the low-tech product generates more factor income than would be generated by one<br />

high-tech producer and all other resources devoted to low-tech production (see<br />

figure). Since the function λ(h) c(<br />

z)<br />

gives the unit labor requirements for intermediate<br />

⎛<br />

−1<br />

⎞<br />

⎜<br />

⎟<br />

production, and λ '(<br />

h)<br />

< 0 , the φ r wλ( h)<br />

c(<br />

z)<br />

nσ<br />

−1<br />

⎜ ,<br />

⎟ = π contour shifts outward when<br />

⎝<br />

⎠<br />

the human capital stock increases. Thus, if subsidies to human capital accumulation<br />

increase h, they may do nothing to the equilibrium (small shift), lead to a diversified<br />

economy (shift to dotted isocost line), or lead to specialization in high tech goods (shift<br />

to heavy dotted line). Although the graph does not reveal it, n adjusts if the nature of<br />

the equilibrium changes. Not also that the latter two shocks eliminate the low- tech<br />

equilibrium, so that coordination is no longer an issue.


Part II: Answer either of the following two questions<br />

3) (25 minutes) Some economists have argued that unusually rapid factor accumulation has<br />

driven growth among the countries that have successfully developed during the past 30<br />

years. (See, for <strong>exam</strong>ple, Alwyn Young, “The Tyranny of Numbers, . . .” and Gregory<br />

Mankiw, David Romer and David Weil, “A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic<br />

Growth.”) Others have argued that productivity growth has been the key to their<br />

success⎯perhaps reflecting successful escape from a poverty trap. (See, for <strong>exam</strong>ple,<br />

Peter Kenow and Andrés Rodriguez-Clare, “Has the Neoclassical Revolution Gone too<br />

Far?”)<br />

a) Describe and critically evaluate the methodologies that these authors have used to<br />

arrive at their conclusions.<br />

Young uses a total factor productivity decomposition based on the total differential of<br />

a neoclassical production function:<br />

∆ ln( A ) = ∆ ln( Y<br />

t<br />

t<br />

/ L ) −<br />

t<br />

[ s ∆ ln( K / L )]<br />

K<br />

t<br />

t<br />

⎡<br />

− ⎢s<br />

⎢⎣<br />

K<br />

⎛ K<br />

∆ ln⎜<br />

⎝ K<br />

*<br />

t<br />

t<br />

⎞<br />

⎟<br />

+ s<br />

⎠<br />

L<br />

*<br />

⎛ Lt<br />

∆ ln⎜<br />

⎝ Lt<br />

⎞⎤<br />

⎟<br />

⎥<br />

⎠⎥⎦<br />

Here A represents the productivity level, s ’s are factor shares in total cost, and<br />

variables <strong>with</strong> asterisks are quality adjusted input measures. The expression states<br />

that growth in output per worker is due to (1) increases in the capital labor ratio, (2)<br />

increases in the quality of inputs, or (3) growth in total factor productivity. Applying<br />

this decomposition to data from the gang of 4 countries, he finds that their productivity<br />

growth performance, while solid, was not extraordinary. Hence he concludes that<br />

these countries grew exceptionally rapidly simply because they accumulated factors<br />

and improved factors at an exceptional pace.<br />

Easterly and Levine complain that Young’s study would attribute growth to factor<br />

accumulation even if it were induced by productivity growth. So this study may not be<br />

the best way to sort out whether productivity growth is key. To get around this<br />

critique, Mankiw, Romer and Weil assume a Cobb-Douglas technology that includes<br />

labor, human capital, and physical capital: Y = C + I<br />

Y ⎛<br />

which implies = A⎜<br />

L ⎝<br />

K<br />

Y<br />

⎞<br />

⎟<br />

⎠<br />

1<br />

α<br />

−α−β<br />

⎛<br />

⎜<br />

⎝<br />

H<br />

Y<br />

⎞<br />

⎟<br />

⎠<br />

1<br />

β<br />

−α−β<br />

α β 1−α−β<br />

K + I H = K H (AL) ,<br />

= AX . Then using the steady state savings<br />

rates in physical and human capital they obtain<br />

K I K / Y<br />

= and<br />

H I H / Y<br />

= ,<br />

Y g + δ + n Y g + δ + n<br />

which substituted into the previous expression yield an equation for per worker<br />

income in terms of investment rates in physical and human capital when all lower-case<br />

and Greek characters are treated as parameters. This expression explains a large<br />

fraction (74 percent) of the cross-country variation in per worker income, so they<br />

conclude that factor accumulation is the key to living standards. Kenow and


Rodriguez-Clare question this conclusion on two counts: they complain that MRW<br />

didn’t include primary education in their measure of human capital investment, and<br />

they say that the technology which converts output to physical capital isn’t the same as<br />

the technology that converts output to human capital. Re-doing the exercise, they<br />

reduce explain variation to 40 percent, and argue that productivity differences are an<br />

important part of the recipe for success.<br />

b) Does the debate boil down to disagreement about whether savings causes growth or<br />

responds to it? Explain.<br />

4) (25 minutes) Below are some commonly held beliefs about the typical transition from<br />

extreme poverty to industrialized status. Critically evaluate the empirical evidence on each<br />

statement, and indicate whether you feel it is valid. Pay attention to empirical<br />

methodologies.<br />

a) (8 points) Income distribution becomes relatively less equal before it improves.<br />

The early literature on inequality and development found this pattern, but it was based<br />

on cross-sectional analysis of poor data. It largely reflected the fact that Latin<br />

American countries were in the middle of the per capita income range and they had<br />

relatively unequal (measured) income distributions. More recent studies that follow<br />

countries through time (pooling countries and including country dummy variables)<br />

tend not to find any relationship between per capita income and growth; a few even<br />

find that growth makes the distribution more equal.<br />

b) (8 points) Countries starting from low per capita income levels grow relatively rapidly,<br />

then slow down.<br />

Prior to entering the “intensive growth” phase, many countries spend years in low<br />

level poverty traps. When they begin to develop, growth accelerates, and after the<br />

transition period, they settle down into long-run positive growth. It is also true that,<br />

looking across countries that span a wide range of income levels, growth regressions<br />

usually find a negative relationship between initial per capita GDP and subsequent<br />

growth. However, this at least partly reflects the fact that initial per capita GDP<br />

figures negatively into per capita growth by construction.<br />

c) (8 points) Falling fertility rates typically precede the “intensive growth” phase, during<br />

which per capita output growth accelerates.<br />

No, a country enters the intensive growth phase, morbidity falls first as health<br />

conditions improve. The fertility rate starts to fall later, so there is an early transition<br />

period during which population growth accelerates.


d) (8 points) Despite growth in per capita incomes, poor countries have been getting<br />

poorer relative to rich countries.<br />

As Pritchett documents, the less developed countries have been growing more slowly<br />

that the advanced capitalist countries during the past century. Many of the poor<br />

countries that have experienced the lowest growth rates haven’t kept good data, so the<br />

contrast in performance is probably less dramatic than it would be if it were based on<br />

the full sample of countries.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!