28.01.2015 Views

Homework Assignment #1: Answer Key

Homework Assignment #1: Answer Key

Homework Assignment #1: Answer Key

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Econ 497A<br />

Energy Economics and Energy Security<br />

Professor Ickes<br />

Fall 2011<br />

<strong>Homework</strong> <strong>Assignment</strong> <strong>#1</strong>: <strong>Answer</strong> <strong>Key</strong><br />

1. Suppose that the aggregate production function for the economy, = ( ) was Leontief<br />

— that is the elasticity of substitution between and was zero. What does this imply<br />

Brief <strong>Answer</strong> Zero elasticity of substitution means that there are no possibilities of substituting<br />

inputs. Isoquants are L-shaped. We could write =min ³ <br />

´ <br />

where and are<br />

technologically determined constants. Notice that is thus equal to the unit requirements<br />

of capital per unit of output, for example. Suppose doubles but remains constant.<br />

Then output will not increase.<br />

(a) Now suppose that one of the factors, say , became increasingly scarce. What would<br />

happen to the share of national income that would go to labor over time Explain.<br />

brief answer If labor becomes increasingly scare the wage will increase relative to the<br />

priceofcapital. Sinceincomecannotincreaseif is fixed must increase. So<br />

<br />

labor’s share of income is rising.<br />

(b) Suppose that the elasticity of substitution was extremely high (close to infinity). What<br />

would this imply about the returns going to labor if it became exceedingly scarce Explain.<br />

brief answer If the elasticity of substitution () is extremely high then it is easy to<br />

substitute capital for labor. The production function with = ∞ leads to an isoquant<br />

that is linear. So the production function could be written as = + . Wecan<br />

substitute for without any changes in their marginal products. So the prices of<br />

the factors will not change. If is increasing due to labor scarcity, but it is easy to<br />

<br />

substitute capital for labor, the wage will not rise relative to the price of capital, so<br />

will fall.<br />

<br />

<br />

(c) Now suppose that as labor became more scarce its share of national income was unchanged.<br />

What would the elasticity of substitution be in this case<br />

brief answer If the share of national income is unchanged when labor becomes more<br />

scarce it must mean that the wage must rise in exact proportion to the fall in labor.<br />

Obviously this means that 0 ∞, from our answers to parts a and b. More<br />

specifically, it means that =1 The elasticity of substitution is the elasticity of the<br />

ratio of two inputs to a production function with respect to the ratio of their marginal<br />

products. If the ratio of the marginal products changes exactly in proportion to the<br />

ratio of the inputs then =1<br />

1


2. (This question appears more difficult than it really is. Just read carefully, and follow along.<br />

There are no mysteries here, but some interesting ideas.) Consider an economy with a production<br />

function, = ( ) 1−− ,where is resources used in production, all other<br />

variables are as usual, and are positive and + 1. Labor supply grows at the constant<br />

rate, , and grows at the constant rate . We consume resources over time, so the growth<br />

rate of ( ∆ )=−, where is a positive constant. From the production function it follows<br />

<br />

that the growth rate of income is given by:<br />

= + +(1− − )[ + ] (1)<br />

where isthegrowthrateofincomeattime, etc. We are interested in a balanced growth<br />

path where all the variables are growing at a constant rate and and grow at the same<br />

rate. Using (1) solve for the balanced growth rate of income, <br />

in terms of the parameters<br />

of the model. Show that <br />

is increasing in , for example.<br />

brief answer By definition on a balanced growth path and aregrowingatthesamerate.<br />

So = so using this in (1) we have:<br />

<br />

= <br />

+ +(1− − )[ + ]<br />

= <br />

− +(1− − )[ + ] (2)<br />

where the second line follows from the definitions of the growth rates in the problem.<br />

Solving (2) for <br />

yields:<br />

<br />

<br />

− <br />

= (1− − )[ + ] − <br />

(1 − − )[ + ] − <br />

=<br />

1 − <br />

addition after class, Sept 22 I really should not have asked you do show that <br />

is increasing<br />

in First, you would need calculus which is not required for the course, and<br />

second if you did differentiate (3) with respect to you would find it is negative not<br />

positive. What I meant to ask is show that <br />

is increasing in or and decreasing in<br />

That would have been a better and easier question. I will grade accordingly.<br />

(a) What happens to <br />

<br />

if increases. Why How does <br />

vary with <br />

brief answer If increases resources are declining at a faster rate. From (3) it is<br />

apparent that <br />

falls. We can also see that if rises, so growth is more sensitive<br />

to resources, then <br />

also falls.<br />

(b) The growth rate of output per worker is just − , so using your expression for <br />

<br />

what is the expression for the growth rate of output per worker on the balanced growth<br />

path, <br />

<br />

Is this necessarily positive Explain.<br />

brief answer Start with (3), and note that − = − , so<br />

<br />

− ≡ − +(1− − )[ + ]<br />

<br />

= − <br />

1 − <br />

− +(1− − )[ + ]<br />

= − 1 − <br />

1 − <br />

1 − <br />

2<br />

(3)


=<br />

− +(1− − )[ + ] − (1 − )<br />

1 − <br />

=<br />

− +(1− − ) − <br />

1 − <br />

=<br />

(1 − − ) − ( + )<br />

1 − <br />

(4)<br />

from (4) it is apparent that the numerator can be positive or negative. If → 0<br />

then <br />

<br />

is necessarily positive. If 0 then <br />

<br />

could be negative if resources<br />

growth is sufficiently negative, for example. That is if is large enough. Intuitively,<br />

if growth is sensitive to resources large and if resources are getting more scarce, it<br />

can offset the benefits of technical progress, .<br />

(c) Suppose there were resources were not fixed; instead suppose that they grow at the same<br />

rate as population, so ∆<br />

<br />

= . What would your expression for the balanced growth<br />

path of output per worker (call it e <br />

)looklikenow<br />

brief answer Now resources are growing, so replace − with in (4), so we have<br />

e (1 − − ) − ( − )<br />

<br />

=<br />

1 − <br />

(1 − − )<br />

= (5)<br />

1 − <br />

Resource growth is exactly offsetting the impact of labor growth in the expression.<br />

Now the growth rate of per-capita income on the balanced growth path is necessarily<br />

positive, because resources are always being augmented, and this offsets the negative<br />

impact of population growth on per-capita income growth.<br />

(d) Define the ”growth drag” from finite resources as the differencebetweengrowthinthe<br />

hypothetical case of part (c) and the actual case of part (b). That is = e <br />

− .<br />

What is equal to Why is this likely to be a pretty small number<br />

brief answer Using (4) and (5) we have<br />

=<br />

=<br />

(1 − − )<br />

−<br />

1 − <br />

( + )<br />

1 − <br />

(1 − − ) − ( + )<br />

1 − <br />

Parameters and are growth rates, numbers like 03 or something, is capital’s<br />

share something like .4 or something, and is by definition less than one. So the<br />

numerator is on the order of (2)(02 + 03) = 01 so is equal to something like<br />

1<br />

(01) ≈ 00167. Per-capita income growth tends to be much larger — at least an<br />

1−4<br />

order of magnitude; for example, in the US per-capita income growth has averaged<br />

about 2% since 1959. The key point is that the drag from resources is likely to be<br />

small, as long as is not very large.<br />

(e) Expression (1) seems to indicate that if income is growing today, it will continue to grow<br />

even as → 0. Why is this the case in this model What does the production function<br />

imply about the elasticity of substitution<br />

(6)<br />

3


ief answer It must mean that the elasticity of substitution is at least unity. We can<br />

substitute other inputs for declining resources without output falling. In fact, the<br />

production function we have chosen has =1. We have assumed that resources are<br />

notabindingconstraintongrowth. Butif1 then the share going to resource<br />

owners would rise as resources became more scarce — in other words, would increase<br />

as declined. So would not be a constant in (6), and thus your answer to part d<br />

understates the effect of declining resources in the case where substitution is difficult.<br />

We know from problem 1 that if production was Leontief then the share of national<br />

income that would go to resource owners would increase dramatically as → 0<br />

As your analysis in problem 1 shows, if =0then the share of income that goes<br />

tothescarceresourcegoesto100%,so −→ 1, and the drag approaches + ,<br />

which would overwhelm all sources of growth (it would still be true if 0 1).<br />

This is clearly a result that is consistent with the apocalyptic intuition about resource<br />

scarcity. When I wrote the production function as = ( ) 1−− I, in fact,<br />

assumed that =1(with such a production function, called Cobb-Douglas, the factor<br />

shares are independent of the capital labor ratio), as the shares and are constant.<br />

But, in fact, we know that the share of income going to resource owners has actually<br />

been falling in the US during the 20th century (real oil prices, for example, have<br />

been roughly constant and energy consumption per unit of GDP has been falling).<br />

So rather than 1 it seems almost certain that 1, and that the small drag<br />

computed in part d is closer to the truth.<br />

3. Consider the basic Hotelling model of exhaustible resources. Assume a competitive economy<br />

with many producers, a fixed cost of extraction, , and a choke price, . The rate of interest<br />

is given at rate . What happens to the extraction path of the resource (the plot of output,<br />

,againsttime)if:<br />

(a) the rate of interest falls.<br />

brief answer In class we analyzed a rise in , so this case is exactly opposite. If <br />

falls, it is all of a sudden better to keep a dollar’s worth of oil in the ground than a<br />

dollar in the bank. So oil production falls. This causes 0 to rise and 0 to fall. The<br />

Hotelling Rule requires that net rent grows at the rate of interest which is now lower.<br />

So clearly the time to exhaustion must rise. If price starts lower than before, and if<br />

it grows slower than before, it must take longer to reach Economically, the present<br />

value of future production has increased, so we should shift extraction towards the<br />

future (see figure 1).<br />

(b) the demand for the resource increases suddenly.<br />

brief answer If the choke price remains unchanged this means that the demand curve<br />

becomes flatter — greater demand at any price below In the case of the inverse<br />

demand curve used in class, = − , this means that falls. If the price path<br />

did not change we would extract more very period and total production would exceed<br />

. So 0 must rise to dampen down the quantity demanded. Since prices still grow<br />

at the rate it follows that 0 must also rise. If not, then we would reach before<br />

exhaustion. You can also see this from the expression we derived in class for output:<br />

= [1 − (1 + )− ],soif falls is higher. But this means that we must reach<br />

4


q t<br />

q 0<br />

initial optimal<br />

extraction path<br />

q <br />

0<br />

new optimal<br />

extraction path<br />

T<br />

T '<br />

t<br />

Figure 1: Shift in the Extraction Path<br />

exhaustion at a lower , so the new extraction path must have higher 0 and lower<br />

.<br />

(c) the choke price falls<br />

brief answer This means that is lower. If the price path were unchanged we would end<br />

up with extra oil which cannot be optimal. So 0 must fall and 0 must increase. The<br />

time to exhaustion must also fall, since reaches the new lower in less periods.<br />

So 0 rises and falls.<br />

(d) a tax on the sales (gross revenue) of the resource, per barrel is imposed on producers.<br />

brief answer This is a tax on revenues, not on rents. So the producer is now equating<br />

(1 − ) − = (1 − ) +1 − <br />

1+<br />

(7)<br />

thetaxisclearlynotneutral(asitwouldbeifthetaxwereonrents,thenwecould<br />

cancel out the (1 − ) terms). The impact of the tax is to lower the present value<br />

of current profits relative to future profits, as the left-hand side of (7) fall by more<br />

than the RHS. So the producer wants to produce less in the current period. So 0<br />

falls. Since production is moved to the future the time to exhaustion must rise, since<br />

prices still rise at the rate of interest.<br />

(e) a new discovery of oil takes place that doubles reserves.<br />

brief answer If reserves now equal 2, then production must rise. But if the choke<br />

price is unchanged and prices grow at the rate of interest, then 0 must rise and <br />

must increase as wellhso that the total amount of production Σ =0 −1 must rise. But<br />

we know that = i 2 1 − (1 + )<br />

−<br />

then the sum of production is given by:<br />

Σ =0 −1 = Σ =0<br />

−1 <br />

2 [1 − (1 + )− ]=<br />

so if doubles, and is given, the only thing that can rise is .<br />

5

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!