09.11.2012 Views

Technische Universität München Credit as an Asset Class - risklab

Technische Universität München Credit as an Asset Class - risklab

Technische Universität München Credit as an Asset Class - risklab

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Technische</strong> <strong>Universität</strong> <strong>München</strong><br />

Zentrum Mathematik<br />

<strong>Credit</strong> <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> <strong>Asset</strong> Cl<strong>as</strong>s<br />

M<strong>as</strong>ter Thesis<br />

of<br />

Barbara Mayer<br />

Supervisors: Prof. Dr. Rudi Zagst<br />

<strong>Technische</strong> <strong>Universität</strong> <strong>München</strong><br />

Anna Kalem<strong>an</strong>ova<br />

Date Due: 21/03/2007<br />

<strong>risklab</strong> germ<strong>an</strong>y GmbH, <strong>München</strong>


I confirm that I have done this thesis on my own <strong>an</strong>d that I have only used the cited<br />

sources.<br />

Munich, 21/03/2007<br />

i


D<strong>an</strong>ksagungen<br />

Zuallererst möchte ich mich bei der Firma <strong>risklab</strong> germ<strong>an</strong>y GmbH für die Bereitstellung<br />

dieses interess<strong>an</strong>ten und aktuellen Them<strong>as</strong> bed<strong>an</strong>ken. Insbesondere gilt mein D<strong>an</strong>k Frau<br />

Anna Kalem<strong>an</strong>ova, die jederzeit für Fragen und Diskussionen offen war und mir stets mit<br />

wertvollen Anregungen zur Seite st<strong>an</strong>d. Weiterhin möchte ich mich auch bei allen <strong>an</strong>deren<br />

Kollegen bei <strong>risklab</strong> für ihre vielseitige Unterstützung bed<strong>an</strong>ken.<br />

In besonderem Maße möchte ich mich auch bei Prof. Rudi Zagst für die hervorragende<br />

fachliche Betreuung während der Diplomarbeit bed<strong>an</strong>ken, aber auch für die sehr lehrreiche<br />

Her<strong>an</strong>führung <strong>an</strong> fin<strong>an</strong>zmathematische Fragestellungen bereits während des Studiums.<br />

Nicht zuletzt gilt mein D<strong>an</strong>k auch meiner Familie und meinem Freund Norbert, die<br />

mich während meines Studiums, vor allem in sehr <strong>an</strong>strengenden Ph<strong>as</strong>en, in jeglicher<br />

Hinsicht voll und g<strong>an</strong>z unterstützt haben.<br />

ii


Contents<br />

1 Introduction 1<br />

1.1 Motivation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1<br />

1.2 Objectives <strong>an</strong>d Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1<br />

2 <strong>Credit</strong> Risk Tr<strong>an</strong>sfer 4<br />

2.1 <strong>Credit</strong> Risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4<br />

2.1.1 Definition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4<br />

2.1.2 <strong>Credit</strong> Risk <strong>an</strong>d Regulation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5<br />

2.2 Traditional credit related Instruments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6<br />

2.2.1 Lo<strong>an</strong>s . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6<br />

2.2.2 Bonds . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7<br />

2.3 <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10<br />

2.3.1 Definition <strong>an</strong>d Functionality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10<br />

2.3.2 Cl<strong>as</strong>sification according to Risk Category . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12<br />

2.3.3 Re<strong>as</strong>ons for the Utilisation of <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives . . . . . . . . . . . 12<br />

2.3.4 Ch<strong>an</strong>ces <strong>an</strong>d Risks related to <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives Markets . . . . . . 15<br />

2.3.5 Tr<strong>an</strong>saction Costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18<br />

2.3.6 Market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18<br />

2.4 Securitisations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24<br />

2.4.1 Definition <strong>an</strong>d Functionality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24<br />

2.4.2 Cl<strong>as</strong>sification according to the Underlying <strong>Asset</strong> . . . . . . . . . . . 26<br />

2.4.3 Re<strong>as</strong>ons for the Utilisation of Securitisations . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27<br />

2.4.4 Risks related to Securitisation Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28<br />

2.4.5 Tr<strong>an</strong>saction Costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30<br />

2.4.6 Market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30<br />

3 <strong>Credit</strong> Risk Tr<strong>an</strong>sfer Instruments 35<br />

3.1 Derivatives- or Securitisation-b<strong>as</strong>ed Instruments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35<br />

3.2 <strong>Credit</strong> Default Swap/<strong>Credit</strong> Default Option . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36<br />

3.3 Total Return Swap . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38<br />

3.4 <strong>Credit</strong> Spread Option . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40<br />

3.5 B<strong>as</strong>ket <strong>Credit</strong> Default Swap . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40<br />

3.6 Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> Default Swap . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42<br />

3.7 <strong>Credit</strong> Linked Note . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44<br />

3.8 Collateralised Debt Obligation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46<br />

3.8.1 Traditional CDO (True Sales Securitisation) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46<br />

iii


CONTENTS<br />

3.8.2 Synthetic CDO (Synthetic Securitisation) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48<br />

3.8.3 Cl<strong>as</strong>sification of CDO Tr<strong>an</strong>sactions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49<br />

3.9 CDS Indices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50<br />

3.9.1 iTraxx Indices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51<br />

3.9.2 DJ CDX Indices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56<br />

3.9.3 Motivations for Investors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57<br />

3.9.4 Market Particip<strong>an</strong>ts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58<br />

4 Data Analysis 59<br />

4.1 A Note on Return Definitions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59<br />

4.2 US Aggregates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60<br />

4.3 Euro-Aggregates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63<br />

4.4 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66<br />

5 Simulation <strong>an</strong>d Pricing Framework 67<br />

5.1 A Note on Interest-Rate Modelling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67<br />

5.2 Model of Zagst for Economic Scenario Generation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69<br />

5.3 Fitting of the Interest-Rate Curve . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75<br />

5.4 Simulation of Correlated Default Times . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75<br />

5.4.1 Migration Matrices Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76<br />

5.4.2 One-Factor Copula . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80<br />

5.5 Pricing of Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Instruments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90<br />

5.5.1 Zero-Coupon Bonds . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91<br />

5.5.2 Coupon Bonds . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92<br />

5.5.3 Excursus: Default Intensity Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93<br />

5.5.4 Floating Rate Notes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96<br />

5.5.5 Funded CDS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97<br />

5.5.6 Funded CDS Indices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 101<br />

6 Portfolio Selection 106<br />

6.1 Traditional Portfolio Selection . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106<br />

6.1.1 Me<strong>an</strong>-Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106<br />

6.1.2 Problems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109<br />

6.2 Conditional Value at Risk Optimisation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109<br />

6.2.1 A Note on Value at Risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109<br />

6.2.2 Conditional Value at Risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110<br />

6.3 Perform<strong>an</strong>ce Me<strong>as</strong>ure Omega . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111<br />

6.4 Portfolio Selection with Me<strong>as</strong>ure Score . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 112<br />

7 Simulation <strong>an</strong>d Simulation Results 114<br />

7.1 US Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114<br />

7.1.1 Calibration of the Economic Scenario Generator . . . . . . . . . . . 114<br />

7.1.2 Fit to Market Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119<br />

7.1.3 Simulation of Correlated Default Times . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119<br />

7.1.4 Return Characteristics of Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Instruments . . . . . . . . . . . 120<br />

7.1.5 Me<strong>an</strong>-Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131<br />

iv


CONTENTS<br />

7.1.6 Conditional Value at Risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 138<br />

7.1.7 Score . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 144<br />

7.1.8 Comparison of Optimal Portfolios . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 148<br />

7.2 US Economy with Higher Default Correlation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 151<br />

7.2.1 Return Characteristics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 151<br />

7.2.2 Me<strong>an</strong>-Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 160<br />

7.2.3 Conditional Value at Risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165<br />

7.2.4 Score . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 170<br />

7.2.5 Comparison of Optimal Portfolios . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173<br />

8 Summary <strong>an</strong>d Outlook 175<br />

A Mathematical Preliminaries <strong>an</strong>d Definitions 178<br />

A.1 Probability Spaces <strong>an</strong>d Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Processes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 178<br />

A.2 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Differential Equations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 180<br />

A.3 Equivalent Me<strong>as</strong>ure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 182<br />

B Ratings 184<br />

C Calculation of the Dynamics of the CDS Index 185<br />

D Tr<strong>an</strong>sition Matrix for Europe<strong>an</strong> Union 187<br />

E List of Abbreviations 188<br />

Bibliography 189<br />

v


List of Figures<br />

2.1 B<strong>as</strong>ic structure of a credit derivative contract . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11<br />

2.2 Risks covered by credit derivatives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12<br />

2.3 Global credit derivatives market (in USD billions, excluding <strong>as</strong>set swaps) . 19<br />

2.4 Market shares of credit derivatives products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21<br />

2.5 Market shares of reference entities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22<br />

2.6 Reference entities by credit rating . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22<br />

2.7 B<strong>as</strong>ic structure of a securitisation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25<br />

2.8 Cl<strong>as</strong>sification according to the underlying <strong>as</strong>set . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26<br />

2.9 Global securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce (in USD billions) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31<br />

2.10 Global securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce by region (in USD billions) . . . . . . . . . . 32<br />

2.11 Europe<strong>an</strong> securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce by region 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33<br />

2.12 US securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce by collateral 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33<br />

2.13 Europe<strong>an</strong> securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce by collateral 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34<br />

3.1 Derivatives- or securitisation-b<strong>as</strong>ed credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer instruments . . . . . 35<br />

3.2 <strong>Credit</strong> default swap . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36<br />

3.3 Total return swap . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39<br />

3.4 <strong>Credit</strong> linked note . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44<br />

3.5 Collateralised lo<strong>an</strong> obligation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46<br />

3.6 Collateralised synthetic lo<strong>an</strong> obligation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48<br />

3.7 iTraxx Europe index family . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51<br />

3.8 Spread history iTraxx Europe, 5 years term . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55<br />

3.9 Spread history DJ CDX.NA.IG, 5 years term . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57<br />

4.1 QQ-plots of US aggregates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61<br />

4.2 Histogram of US aggregates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62<br />

4.3 QQ-plots of Euro-aggregates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64<br />

4.4 Histogram of Euro-aggregates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65<br />

5.1 Model of Zagst . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70<br />

5.2 Nelson-Siegel interest-rate curves . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76<br />

5.3 <strong>Credit</strong> curve (Q (R) (t))0≤t≤400 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80<br />

5.4 Densities of NIG distribution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84<br />

5.5 Correlated default times with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d NIG one-factor copula model . 88<br />

5.6 One-factor Gaussi<strong>an</strong> copula vs. one-factor NIG copula . . . . . . . . . . . . 89<br />

5.7 Compounding of recovery payment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91<br />

vi


LIST OF FIGURES<br />

5.8 Coupon payment structure of a coupon bond . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92<br />

5.9 Possible c<strong>as</strong>h flow structure of a FRN . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96<br />

5.10 Coupon payment structure of a CDS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98<br />

5.11 Compounding of recovery payment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98<br />

5.12 Compounding of recovery payments of a CDS index . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104<br />

6.1 Efficient frontier . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108<br />

7.1 US Tre<strong>as</strong>ury Strips . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115<br />

7.2 US credit spreads, rating cl<strong>as</strong>ses AA, A2, BBB1 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118<br />

7.3 Model fit of US zero rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119<br />

7.4 Key statistics US economy, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124<br />

7.5 Key statistics US economy, NIG defaults . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125<br />

7.6 Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 1 year time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults<br />

(left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126<br />

7.7 Left tail densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 1 year time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 127<br />

7.8 Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments without left tails, 1 year time horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . 127<br />

7.9 Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 3 years time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults<br />

(left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 128<br />

7.10 Left tail densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 3 years time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 129<br />

7.11 Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments without left tails, 3 years time horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . 129<br />

7.12 Correlation of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments in US economy, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults <strong>an</strong>d<br />

NIG defaults . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 130<br />

7.13 Minimum-vari<strong>an</strong>ce portfolio with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d<br />

NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 134<br />

7.14 Results of me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimisation, 1 year investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 135<br />

7.15 Results of me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimisation, 3 years investment horizon with<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . 136<br />

7.16 Results of me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimisation, 5 years investment horizon with<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . 137<br />

7.17 Minimum-CVaR portfolio with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG<br />

defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140<br />

7.18 Results of CVaR optimisation, 1 year investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 141<br />

7.19 Results of CVaR optimisation, 3 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 142<br />

7.20 Results of CVaR optimisation, 5 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 143<br />

7.21 Results of score optimisation, 1 year investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 145<br />

vii


LIST OF FIGURES<br />

7.22 Results of score optimisation, 3 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 146<br />

7.23 Results of score optimisation, 5 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 147<br />

7.24 Results for risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d risk-affine investor, 1 year investment horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (top) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (bottom) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 148<br />

7.25 Results for risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d risk-affine investor, 3 years investment horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (top) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (bottom) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 149<br />

7.26 Results for risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d risk-affine investor, 5 years investment horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (top) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (bottom) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150<br />

7.27 Key statistics US economy, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153<br />

7.28 Key statistics US economy, NIG defaults . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154<br />

7.29 Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 1 year time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults<br />

(left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 155<br />

7.30 Left tail densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 1 year time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 156<br />

7.31 Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments without left tails, 1 year time horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . 156<br />

7.32 Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 3 years time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults<br />

(left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 157<br />

7.33 Left tail densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 3 years time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 158<br />

7.34 Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments without left tails, 3 years time horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . 158<br />

7.35 Correlation of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments in US economy, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults <strong>an</strong>d<br />

NIG defaults . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 159<br />

7.36 Minimum-vari<strong>an</strong>ce portfolio with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d<br />

NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 161<br />

7.37 Results of me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimisation, 1 year investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 162<br />

7.38 Results of me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimisation, 3 years investment horizon with<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . 163<br />

7.39 Results of me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimisation, 5 years investment horizon with<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . 164<br />

7.40 Minimum-CVaR portfolio with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG<br />

defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 166<br />

7.41 Results of CVaR optimisation, 1 year investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 167<br />

7.42 Results of CVaR optimisation, 3 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 168<br />

7.43 Results of CVaR optimisation, 5 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 169<br />

7.44 Results of score optimisation, 1 year investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 170<br />

viii


LIST OF FIGURES<br />

7.45 Results of score optimisation, 3 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 171<br />

7.46 Results of score optimisation, 5 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side) . . . . . . . . . 172<br />

7.47 Results for risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d risk-affine investor, 1 year investment horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (top) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (bottom) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173<br />

7.48 Results for risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d risk-affine investor, 3 years investment horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (top) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (bottom) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 174<br />

7.49 Results for risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d risk-affine investor, 5 years investment horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (top) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (bottom) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 174<br />

ix


List of Tables<br />

2.1 Risks in credit derivatives markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16<br />

2.2 Market shares of main protection buyers <strong>an</strong>d sellers . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20<br />

2.3 Risks in securitisation markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29<br />

3.1 iTraxx Europe by industrial sectors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52<br />

3.2 Issu<strong>an</strong>ce of iTraxx Europe series . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55<br />

3.3 Fixed spreads <strong>an</strong>d recovery rates of iTraxx Europe series 6 . . . . . . . . . . 55<br />

3.4 DJ CDX Indices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56<br />

4.1 US Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61<br />

4.2 Jarque-Bera test for US Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63<br />

4.3 Jarque-Bera test for US Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates (log returns) . . . . . . . . . . 63<br />

4.4 Euro-Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64<br />

4.5 Jarque-Bera test for Euro-Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65<br />

4.6 Jarque-Bera test for Euro-Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates (log returns) . . . . . . . . . 65<br />

5.1 US average one-year probability of default, 1981 to 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . 77<br />

5.2 US average one-year tr<strong>an</strong>sition rates, 1981 to 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77<br />

5.3 Log-exp<strong>an</strong>sion of M . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79<br />

7.1 Parameter estimation for processes r <strong>an</strong>d ω . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115<br />

7.2 Parameter estimation for processes s <strong>an</strong>d u for rating cl<strong>as</strong>ses AA, A2, BBB1116<br />

7.3 Composition of US CDS index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116<br />

7.4 Parameter estimation for process i . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117<br />

7.5 Parameters for US equity process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117<br />

7.6 Nelson-Siegel parameters for US zero rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119<br />

7.7 Parameters of NIG distribution for US economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119<br />

7.8 Characterisation of representative investors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 144<br />

B.1 St<strong>an</strong>dard & Poor’s credit ratings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 184<br />

D.1 Europe<strong>an</strong> Union average one-year tr<strong>an</strong>sition rates, 1981 to 2005 . . . . . . . 187<br />

x


Chapter 1<br />

Introduction<br />

1.1 Motivation<br />

The credit market h<strong>as</strong> experienced <strong>an</strong> enormous growth over the l<strong>as</strong>t years. As part of the<br />

credit market, the credit derivatives market is the worldwide f<strong>as</strong>test growing derivatives<br />

market. 1 It exp<strong>an</strong>ded from USD 180 billion of outst<strong>an</strong>ding contracts on a total notional<br />

amounts b<strong>as</strong>is in 1997 to USD 5,021 billion in 2004 <strong>an</strong>d to estimated USD 8,206 billion in<br />

2006. 2 After a st<strong>an</strong>dardisation of credit derivative contracts <strong>an</strong>d the introduction of CDS 3<br />

indices, a revolution in terms of liquidity h<strong>as</strong> taken place. The improved liquidity is only<br />

one re<strong>as</strong>on why credit instruments are very attractive to investors.<br />

In addition, credit instruments, such <strong>as</strong> corporate bonds, credit derivatives <strong>an</strong>d securi-<br />

tisations, often have <strong>an</strong> appealing risk-return profile, allowing to enh<strong>an</strong>ce portfolio return.<br />

Furthermore, due to the correlation structure of their returns to returns of traditional <strong>as</strong>set<br />

cl<strong>as</strong>ses, such <strong>as</strong> stocks <strong>an</strong>d government bonds, they offer high potential for diversification.<br />

Finally, they allow to m<strong>an</strong>age credit risk exposure by hedging credit risk.<br />

Even knowing the potential benefits <strong>an</strong>d risks of different credit instruments, m<strong>an</strong>y<br />

investors still have to become familiar with these instruments <strong>an</strong>d have to learn how to<br />

combine them optimally with traditional <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses, i.e. they have to know the optimal<br />

proportion of credit instruments, especially for their individual level of risk-aversion.<br />

1.2 Objectives <strong>an</strong>d Structure<br />

With this thesis, we w<strong>an</strong>t to contribute to a deep underst<strong>an</strong>ding of credit related prod-<br />

ucts, particularly credit derivatives <strong>an</strong>d securitisations. For this purpose, the reader shall<br />

underst<strong>an</strong>d the drivers <strong>an</strong>d the need for credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer. He also shall underst<strong>an</strong>d the<br />

functionality of various products <strong>an</strong>d the risks inherent in them. Furthermore, we w<strong>an</strong>t<br />

to give <strong>an</strong> idea of the size <strong>an</strong>d the impressive development of the market.<br />

Besides, we also aim at <strong>an</strong>alysing credit instruments in a portfolio context with tradi-<br />

tional <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses. Therefore, we introduce <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set allocation framework with a scenario-<br />

1 See [BR04], p. 16.<br />

2 See [Bri04], p. 5 <strong>an</strong>d [Fit05], p. 1.<br />

3 A credit default swap (CDS) is a contract in which the protection buyer pays a fixed periodic fee on<br />

the notional amount to the protection seller over a predetermined period. In exch<strong>an</strong>ge, the protection<br />

buyer receives a contingent payment from the protection seller, triggered by a credit event of a reference<br />

entity.<br />

1


CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION<br />

b<strong>as</strong>ed simulation of risk factors on the one h<strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>d a simulation of default times on the<br />

other h<strong>an</strong>d. Then, risk factors <strong>an</strong>d default times are used to price various credit instru-<br />

ments. After having determined the return distribution of the government bonds, the<br />

equity index <strong>an</strong>d the credit instruments, we are able to calculate optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocations<br />

with several optimisation criteria. We do not only apply traditional portfolio optimisation<br />

according to Markowitz 4 , but also optimisations, b<strong>as</strong>ed on other criteria that are able to<br />

better capture the distinct distributional properties of credit instruments. That way, we<br />

c<strong>an</strong> show that investors benefit from adding credit instruments to their portfolio, i.e. with<br />

the same level of risk they c<strong>an</strong> generate a higher expected return.<br />

To reach the objectives listed above, we chose the following structure of the thesis.<br />

Chapter 2 gives a general introduction into credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer. After defining credit<br />

risk <strong>an</strong>d explaining some regulatory <strong>as</strong>pects, we briefly describe traditional credit related<br />

instruments, lo<strong>an</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d bonds. Then, we introduce the two main possibilities of credit<br />

risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer, credit derivatives <strong>an</strong>d securitisations. We describe their functionality, the<br />

re<strong>as</strong>ons for using credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer instruments, <strong>an</strong>d both, ch<strong>an</strong>ces <strong>an</strong>d risks related to<br />

these markets. Finally, we give <strong>an</strong> overview on market evolution <strong>an</strong>d size.<br />

In Chapter 3, single credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer instruments are explained in their b<strong>as</strong>ic form,<br />

but also some product variations. In particular, we introduce CDS, total return swaps,<br />

credit spread options, b<strong>as</strong>ket CDS, portfolio CDS, credit linked notes, collateralised debt<br />

obligations <strong>an</strong>d CDS indices.<br />

In order to learn more about distributional properties of the returns of credit instru-<br />

ments, we <strong>an</strong>alyse Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregate indices, which are fixed income indices, in Chapter<br />

4.<br />

In Chapter 5 we introduce a model for scenario generation. It h<strong>as</strong> a c<strong>as</strong>cade form,<br />

incorporating macro-economic factors to simulate interest-rates <strong>an</strong>d equity indices. To<br />

realistically price credit instruments, we need to take into account potential defaults.<br />

The one-factor copula approach for modelling correlated default times between reference<br />

entities h<strong>as</strong> become very popular. We use this approach not only for a Gaussi<strong>an</strong> one-<br />

factor copula, but also for a Normal-Inverse-Gaussi<strong>an</strong> one-factor copula, which is able to<br />

produce more realistic properties for default times th<strong>an</strong> the Gaussi<strong>an</strong> version, such <strong>as</strong> a<br />

higher probability of joint defaults of different comp<strong>an</strong>ies. The l<strong>as</strong>t section is dedicated to<br />

the pricing formul<strong>as</strong> for the credit instruments in the investment universe. In particular,<br />

these instruments are zero-coupon bonds, coupon bonds, funded CDS <strong>an</strong>d funded CDS<br />

indices.<br />

Chapter 6 deals with portfolio selection. As a first step, the me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce approach<br />

according to Markowitz <strong>an</strong>d its problems due to strict <strong>as</strong>sumptions on the structure of<br />

<strong>as</strong>set returns or on utility functions is described. Then, we introduce the optimisation with<br />

the conditional value at risk <strong>as</strong> risk me<strong>as</strong>ure. Finally, we present the portfolio selection<br />

with the me<strong>as</strong>ure score taking into account <strong>an</strong> investor’s risk-aversion. In this context, we<br />

<strong>as</strong>sume two representative investors, one being risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d the other being risk-affine.<br />

We apply our <strong>as</strong>set allocation framework to investors in the United States in Chapter<br />

7. At first, we present the simulation parameters, the return statistics for the instruments<br />

under consideration <strong>an</strong>d the optimisation results with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d NIG default times.<br />

4 See [Mar52].<br />

2


CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION<br />

For all selection criteria, we examine optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocations with different investment<br />

universes <strong>an</strong>d different investment horizons. As market implied default correlations be-<br />

tween reference entities <strong>as</strong> per 30 th of September, 2006 (simulation start date) is rather<br />

low, we also perform <strong>an</strong> optimisation for a higher default correlation. The results c<strong>an</strong> be<br />

found in the second part of the chapter. Particularly, we work out the main characteristics<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the main differences to the results with the market-implied default correlation.<br />

fields.<br />

Chapter 8 summarises the results of this thesis <strong>an</strong>d gives <strong>an</strong> outlook on further research<br />

3


Chapter 2<br />

<strong>Credit</strong> Risk Tr<strong>an</strong>sfer<br />

To obtain a deeper underst<strong>an</strong>ding of credit related products, it is necessary to underst<strong>an</strong>d<br />

credit risk <strong>as</strong> such, <strong>an</strong>d the drivers <strong>an</strong>d the need for credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer. This chapter<br />

provides <strong>an</strong> introduction into credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer.<br />

Section 2.1 covers credit risk. After having defined credit risk <strong>an</strong>d its elements, we<br />

explain how credit risk is embedded into regulation <strong>an</strong>d its import<strong>an</strong>ce for regulation.<br />

The traditional credit related instruments, lo<strong>an</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d bonds, are described in Section 2.2.<br />

They often serve <strong>as</strong> underlying for credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer. The two following sections are<br />

dedicated to the main possibilities of credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer. Section 2.3 deals with credit<br />

derivatives. It describes their functionality, the risk categories, which c<strong>an</strong> be covered<br />

with them, the re<strong>as</strong>ons for their utilisation, <strong>an</strong>d the ch<strong>an</strong>ces <strong>an</strong>d risks related to these<br />

markets. A brief paragraph regarding tr<strong>an</strong>saction costs c<strong>an</strong> be found <strong>as</strong> well <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> extensive<br />

description of the size <strong>an</strong>d evolution of the market. Section 2.4 covers securitisation. First,<br />

a securitisation is described in its b<strong>as</strong>ic form. After having given a cl<strong>as</strong>sification according<br />

to possible underlying <strong>as</strong>sets <strong>an</strong>d re<strong>as</strong>ons for the utilisation of securitisations, the risks<br />

related to these markets are explained. Then, a brief paragraph regarding tr<strong>an</strong>saction<br />

costs follows. The section closes with a description of the size <strong>an</strong>d the evolution of the<br />

securitisation market.<br />

2.1 <strong>Credit</strong> Risk<br />

2.1.1 Definition<br />

<strong>Credit</strong> risk c<strong>an</strong> be defined <strong>as</strong> the ”risk of ch<strong>an</strong>ges in value <strong>as</strong>sociated with unexpected<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the credit quality” 1 of a counterparty in a fin<strong>an</strong>cial contract. These unexpected<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ges r<strong>an</strong>ge from a reduction in the market value of the fin<strong>an</strong>cial contract to the default<br />

of the counterparty, which is the inability of the obligor to meet payment obligations.<br />

Considering credit risk in more detail, one c<strong>an</strong> differentiate between the following<br />

individual risk elements:<br />

• Default probability – the probability that the counterparty will default on its con-<br />

tractual obligations to pay back the debt.<br />

1 See [DS03], p. 3.<br />

4


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

• Recovery rates – the fraction of the nominal amount which may be recovered in c<strong>as</strong>e<br />

of counterparty default.<br />

• <strong>Credit</strong> migration – the expected ch<strong>an</strong>ges in credit quality of the obligor or counter-<br />

party.<br />

Furthermore, there are portfolio risk elements:<br />

• Default <strong>an</strong>d credit quality correlation – the degree of correlation between default or<br />

credit quality of one obligor <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>other.<br />

• Risk contribution <strong>an</strong>d credit concentration – the contribution of one instrument in<br />

the portfolio to the overall portfolio risk. 2<br />

2.1.2 <strong>Credit</strong> Risk <strong>an</strong>d Regulation<br />

Bearing credit risk is <strong>an</strong> essential part of b<strong>an</strong>king <strong>an</strong>d a signific<strong>an</strong>t source of income<br />

for fin<strong>an</strong>cial institutions. Consequently, it is import<strong>an</strong>t to monitor <strong>an</strong>d m<strong>an</strong>age the risk<br />

positions in the portfolio continuously. In order to have a diversified credit portfolio, it<br />

is crucial to avoid concentration of credit risk vis-à-vis a client or <strong>an</strong> industry. This is<br />

vital for each single fin<strong>an</strong>cial institution in order to reduce its risk of fin<strong>an</strong>cial distress <strong>an</strong>d<br />

thus ensuring the stability of the fin<strong>an</strong>cial system, which is finally the main re<strong>as</strong>on for<br />

regulation.<br />

1988 B<strong>as</strong>el Accord<br />

According to the 1988 B<strong>as</strong>el Accord, b<strong>an</strong>ks have to hold capital in reserve – the so-<br />

called regulatory capital – in order to be able to offset losses resulting from credit or<br />

market risk. It uses only four different risk weights to distinguish between <strong>as</strong>set categories.<br />

Thus, the risk structure of the <strong>as</strong>sets in a b<strong>an</strong>k’s bal<strong>an</strong>ce sheet determines the minimum<br />

regulatory capital. Vice versa, a given regulatory capital limits risk-bearing credit <strong>an</strong>d<br />

trading tr<strong>an</strong>sactions of a b<strong>an</strong>k. Therefore, b<strong>an</strong>ks have <strong>an</strong> incentive to look for capital<br />

relief, for example by using credit derivatives.<br />

At its inception, this first approach to a risk-b<strong>as</strong>ed supervisory process represented <strong>an</strong><br />

innovative <strong>an</strong>d intelligent way of regulation. In the me<strong>an</strong>time, however, a rapid technolog-<br />

ical <strong>an</strong>d fin<strong>an</strong>cial evolution h<strong>as</strong> taken place, undermining the effectiveness of regulation.<br />

This development dem<strong>an</strong>ded a new, modern framework taking into account the incre<strong>as</strong>ing<br />

number of complex fin<strong>an</strong>cial products, other forms of risk such <strong>as</strong> operational risk, <strong>an</strong>d<br />

risk weights better aligned with actual risk inherent in a b<strong>an</strong>k’s <strong>as</strong>sets.<br />

B<strong>as</strong>el II Accord<br />

In 2004, a new Capital Accord for international operating b<strong>an</strong>ks, the B<strong>as</strong>el II Accord, w<strong>as</strong><br />

p<strong>as</strong>sed. It constitutes a framework b<strong>as</strong>ed on three pillars: Minimum capital requirements,<br />

supervisory review process <strong>an</strong>d enh<strong>an</strong>ced disclosure. The Accord h<strong>as</strong> to be implemented<br />

by the signatory countries by the end of 2006. It c<strong>an</strong> be considered <strong>as</strong> a milestone for the<br />

international harmonisation of regulation. It h<strong>as</strong> to overcome weaknesses of B<strong>as</strong>el I such <strong>as</strong><br />

2 See [BK04], p. 376 <strong>an</strong>d [Sch03], pp. 2-3.<br />

5


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

insufficient coverage of new fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments <strong>an</strong>d insufficient differentiation according<br />

to credit quality of the obligor when calculating the regulatory capital. B<strong>as</strong>el II aims to<br />

consider new developments <strong>an</strong>d innovations in fin<strong>an</strong>cial markets. Furthermore, it aims<br />

to improve risk adjustment of capital requirements <strong>an</strong>d thus alignment of the regulatory<br />

capital with the economic capital – the capital requirement reflecting the actual economic<br />

risk a b<strong>an</strong>k faces. This c<strong>an</strong> be accomplished with more sophisticated me<strong>as</strong>urement ap-<br />

proaches taking into account the credit quality in form of credit ratings of obligors – either<br />

provided by credit rating agencies or b<strong>as</strong>ed on b<strong>an</strong>k-internal ratings – to determine the<br />

risk weights needed for the calculation of regulatory capital. 3 Due to the implementation<br />

of the new Accord, a b<strong>an</strong>k h<strong>as</strong> a higher incentive to monitor <strong>an</strong>d m<strong>an</strong>age the credit risk<br />

exposure more precisely, for example, by using a higher proportion of credit derivatives or<br />

by employing more risk-adjusted pricing when allocating lo<strong>an</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d mortgages.<br />

After having explained credit risk with its components <strong>an</strong>d the import<strong>an</strong>ce of credit<br />

risk for regulation, we now turn to traditional credit related instruments.<br />

2.2 Traditional credit related Instruments<br />

In this section we describe lo<strong>an</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d bonds that often serve <strong>as</strong> underlying <strong>as</strong>set in credit<br />

derivative contracts.<br />

2.2.1 Lo<strong>an</strong>s<br />

Lo<strong>an</strong>s are contracts between two (or more parties) – the borrower or obligor, for example a<br />

corporate entity, <strong>an</strong>d the lender or creditor, typically a b<strong>an</strong>k. In the b<strong>as</strong>ic form, the parties<br />

agree upon the lending of money (the principal or notional amount) by the creditor to the<br />

borrower with the obligation for the latter to pay back the notional amount at maturity.<br />

In the me<strong>an</strong>time, the borrower h<strong>as</strong> to make regular interest payments at predefined dates<br />

in return for the use of someone else’s capital.<br />

Variations on the B<strong>as</strong>ic Structure<br />

The payment from the lender to the borrower c<strong>an</strong> be made in one sum, in partial amounts<br />

or it c<strong>an</strong> be provided in form of a credit line. The borrower c<strong>an</strong> receive the notional<br />

amount at par (at 100%) or with <strong>an</strong> agio (> 100%) or a disagio (< 100%).<br />

Regarding the repayment of the notional amount, we c<strong>an</strong> distinguish between the<br />

repayment<br />

• in one sum at maturity (bullet repayment),<br />

• in regular instalments plus the interest-rate payments for the remaining sum of the<br />

previous period (amortisable lo<strong>an</strong>), or<br />

• in const<strong>an</strong>t regular instalments containing repayment <strong>an</strong>d interest rate payment<br />

(<strong>an</strong>nuity lo<strong>an</strong>). 4<br />

3 For further reading regarding the different me<strong>as</strong>urement approaches in terms of credit risk, such <strong>as</strong> the<br />

St<strong>an</strong>dardized approach <strong>an</strong>d the Internal Ratings B<strong>as</strong>ed approaches, we recommend the original framework<br />

(see [BIS05a]).<br />

4 See [Sch03], p. 10<br />

6


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

Interest-rates c<strong>an</strong> be stipulated fixed or floating. In the c<strong>as</strong>e of floating interest-rates,<br />

there is usually a market interest-rate which is used <strong>as</strong> benchmark (for example LIBOR 5 ).<br />

The obligor h<strong>as</strong> to pay the benchmark rate plus a spread. Furthermore, lo<strong>an</strong>s c<strong>an</strong> be<br />

gr<strong>an</strong>ted unsecured or secured. Real estate or securities often serve <strong>as</strong> collateral.<br />

Apart from the presented specifications, there are much more variations in designing<br />

a lo<strong>an</strong> contract since it is a private agreement <strong>an</strong>d thus very flexible.<br />

Lo<strong>an</strong>s c<strong>an</strong> be cl<strong>as</strong>sified into defaultable or risky lo<strong>an</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d non-defaultable or (default)<br />

risk-free 6 lo<strong>an</strong>s, dependent on the obligor’s credit quality. ”Defaultable” is a term used<br />

for <strong>an</strong>y kind of lo<strong>an</strong> bearing credit risk, while a non-defaultable lo<strong>an</strong> h<strong>as</strong> no credit risk<br />

exposure, since the obligor h<strong>as</strong> the highest credit quality.<br />

Risks related to Lo<strong>an</strong>s<br />

Lenders <strong>an</strong>d obligors are exposed to several risks. Besides credit risk, which is discussed in<br />

Section 2.1.1, there are more risks inherent in lo<strong>an</strong>s. In the following, we give <strong>an</strong> overview<br />

on the most import<strong>an</strong>t ones.<br />

• Interest-rate risk– risk of a potential loss that could arise from a ch<strong>an</strong>ge of the market<br />

interest-rates.<br />

• Currency risk – risk of a potential loss that could arise from <strong>an</strong> adverse price ch<strong>an</strong>ge<br />

of foreign currency.<br />

• Inflation risk – risk of reduced real purch<strong>as</strong>ing power of future payments driven by<br />

inflation.<br />

A lo<strong>an</strong> is the oldest me<strong>an</strong>s of payment obligation <strong>an</strong>d it is still <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t source<br />

of funding. Since lo<strong>an</strong> contracts are often non-st<strong>an</strong>dardised, it is difficult or impossible to<br />

trade single lo<strong>an</strong>s. In contr<strong>as</strong>t, bonds enable investors to trade debt. They are described<br />

in the following section.<br />

2.2.2 Bonds<br />

A bond is a securitised form of a lo<strong>an</strong>. At the issuing of a bond, the bond holder or lender<br />

buys the bond with a certain principal amount 7 from the issuer or borrower either at<br />

par, with <strong>an</strong> agio or a disagio. 8 By issuing bonds, the borrower commits itself to make<br />

stipulated payments comprising the repayment of the principal amount at maturity date<br />

<strong>an</strong>d interest or coupon payments at predefined coupon dates (for example <strong>an</strong>nually or<br />

semi-<strong>an</strong>nually) to the bond holder.<br />

Cl<strong>as</strong>sification of Bonds<br />

Analogous to lo<strong>an</strong>s, bonds c<strong>an</strong> be cl<strong>as</strong>sified into defaultable or risky bonds <strong>an</strong>d non-<br />

defaultable or (default) risk-free bonds. ”Defaultable bond” is a term for <strong>an</strong>y kind of<br />

5 LIBOR is the London InterB<strong>an</strong>k Offered Rate. It represents the interest-rate between b<strong>an</strong>ks.<br />

6 We use the term ”risk-free” if we consider a fin<strong>an</strong>cial instrument to be default risk-free.<br />

7 Analogue to lo<strong>an</strong>s, the principal amount is the amount which the issuer pays back at maturity <strong>an</strong>d<br />

it is the b<strong>as</strong>is for calculating the interest payments. We will also denote it by nominal amount, notional<br />

amount or simply notional.<br />

8 The me<strong>an</strong>ing of ”at par”, ”agio” <strong>an</strong>d ”disagio” is explained in Section 2.2.1.<br />

7


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

bond with the ch<strong>an</strong>ce of a default. If the issuer defaults on its payment obligations, the<br />

investor will suffer a fin<strong>an</strong>cial loss <strong>as</strong> he only receives a recovery payment. Unlike the<br />

defaultable bond, the non-defaultable bond pays the coupons <strong>an</strong>d the notional amount<br />

surely <strong>an</strong>d in time. Hence, ”non-defaultable” me<strong>an</strong>s that the bonds involve no credit risk<br />

exposure since they have the highest credit quality. Nonetheless, the market risk exposure<br />

remains. Tre<strong>as</strong>ury bonds are often considered to be non-defaultable. 9<br />

There are several types of bonds. In the following, we will explain the most import<strong>an</strong>t<br />

ones which are relev<strong>an</strong>t for the scope of the thesis. 10<br />

• Fixed-coupon bonds are bonds with a const<strong>an</strong>t coupon payment throughout their<br />

lifetime. They are the most widespread form of bonds.<br />

• Zero-coupon bonds do not pay <strong>an</strong>y coupon throughout the lifetime. They are issued<br />

at a subst<strong>an</strong>tial discount from par.<br />

• Floating rate notes (FRN) have a time-varying coupon which is linked to a bench-<br />

mark, such <strong>as</strong> LIBOR, plus a const<strong>an</strong>t spread.<br />

From <strong>an</strong> investor’s point of view, buying a FRN primarily me<strong>an</strong>s having <strong>an</strong> exposure to<br />

credit risk, <strong>as</strong> the interest-rate risk is nearly eliminated by the time-varying interest-rate.<br />

Unlike FRN investors, investors buying a fixed-coupon bond or a zero-coupon bond have<br />

<strong>an</strong> exposure to both credit <strong>an</strong>d interest-rate risk 11 . 12<br />

Bond Market Risks<br />

Bond holders are exposed to similar risks <strong>as</strong> already described in Section 2.2.1. Besides<br />

credit risk, which is discussed in Section 2.1.1, there are the following import<strong>an</strong>t risks<br />

inherent in bond markets. 13<br />

• Market risk/interest-rate risk – risk of a potential loss that could arise from <strong>an</strong><br />

adverse ch<strong>an</strong>ge in the price of a security due to ch<strong>an</strong>ges of the market interest-rates.<br />

In bond markets prices vary inversely with market interest-rates: They fall <strong>as</strong> market<br />

interest-rate goes up, <strong>an</strong>d vice-versa.<br />

• Liquidity risk – risk of adversely affecting the market price when trading in large<br />

size.<br />

• Currency risk – risk of a potential loss that could arise from <strong>an</strong> adverse price ch<strong>an</strong>ge<br />

of foreign currency.<br />

• Inflation risk – risk of reduced real purch<strong>as</strong>ing power of future payments driven by<br />

inflation.<br />

9<br />

See [BOW03] p. 4.<br />

10<br />

In addition, there are for example convertible bonds, callable bonds, high yield bonds, subordinated<br />

bonds, perpetual bonds, etc.. For a detailed description we refer to [SB00], pp. 133-137, <strong>an</strong>d to [GP95],<br />

pp. 362-382.<br />

11<br />

The bond market risks are explained below.<br />

12<br />

See [Bom05], p. 45.<br />

13<br />

One c<strong>an</strong> think of m<strong>an</strong>y more risks related to certain types of bonds. Describing all of them would go<br />

beyond the scope of this thesis.<br />

8


<strong>Credit</strong> Spread<br />

CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

The credit spread is me<strong>as</strong>ured <strong>as</strong> excess return of a defaultable bond over the return of<br />

<strong>an</strong> equivalent non-defaultable bond (with respect to a certain maturity, currency, etc.).<br />

In theory, the credit spread represents the credit quality of the issuer that is <strong>as</strong>sessed by<br />

the market. Hence, it compensates the investor for taking over credit risk. Consequently,<br />

a higher probability to default requires a larger credit spread of the bond. In practice,<br />

however, the credit spread may also include non-credit factors such <strong>as</strong> liquidity risk. 14<br />

Rating<br />

Ratings express the opinion of commercial rating agencies such <strong>as</strong> St<strong>an</strong>dard & Poor’s,<br />

Moody’s or Fitch on the obligor’s capacity to meet its fin<strong>an</strong>cial obligations. They are a<br />

naive me<strong>as</strong>ure of <strong>an</strong> issuer’s credit-worthiness <strong>an</strong>d its probability of default <strong>as</strong> they reflect<br />

the average historical frequency of defaults of issuers with the same rating. They are<br />

named ”naive” <strong>as</strong> rating agencies do not suppose credit ratings to be a me<strong>as</strong>ure of default<br />

probability over a predefined time horizon. They also reflect qualitative criteria such <strong>as</strong><br />

m<strong>an</strong>agement quality, tr<strong>an</strong>sparency, product quality, etc., which are at most indirectly<br />

related to default probability. <strong>Credit</strong> ratings are relative me<strong>as</strong>ures of credit quality, <strong>as</strong><br />

they are more stable through business cycles th<strong>an</strong> absolute default probabilities. They do<br />

not reflect the latest information available in the market since they are normally renewed<br />

once a year.<br />

<strong>Credit</strong> ratings express the opinion of the rating agency on the general credit-worthiness<br />

of <strong>an</strong> obligor with respect to a particular debt security or a fin<strong>an</strong>cial obligation.<br />

Note that a credit rating for a debt title c<strong>an</strong> be better or worse th<strong>an</strong> the issuer rating,<br />

for example in the c<strong>as</strong>e of senior or subordinated debt. Thus, issuer ratings have limited<br />

expl<strong>an</strong>ation power with respect to a certain debt title.<br />

<strong>Credit</strong> ratings c<strong>an</strong> roughly be differentiated between investment-grade ratings, which<br />

me<strong>an</strong> a high credit quality of the rating object, <strong>an</strong>d non-investment-grade (also subinvestment-<br />

grade or speculative grade) ratings, which me<strong>an</strong> a low credit quality of the rating object. 15<br />

Finally, we w<strong>an</strong>t to remark that not only issuers <strong>an</strong>d debt titles c<strong>an</strong> be rating objects,<br />

but also countries or single equity titles.<br />

Characteristics of Bonds<br />

The main difference to lo<strong>an</strong>s is the tradeability of bonds which entails the following ad-<br />

v<strong>an</strong>tages:<br />

• Access to the debt market for a much higher number of investors.<br />

• Possibility of small investments.<br />

• No need to hold investment until maturity.<br />

• More st<strong>an</strong>dardised th<strong>an</strong> lo<strong>an</strong>s (in general).<br />

14 See [DS03], p. 156.<br />

15 For a detailed description of the credit ratings, we refer to Appendix B.<br />

9


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

• Informational function of bond prices: They reflect market’s perception of the<br />

lender’s credit risk.<br />

Thus, value is added by using bonds instead of lo<strong>an</strong>s. Moreover, the issuer c<strong>an</strong> raise<br />

capital at better conditions th<strong>an</strong> by individually negotiating with lo<strong>an</strong> creditors. Bond<br />

issu<strong>an</strong>ce, however, is not worthwhile or possible for every kind of borrower. Bonds c<strong>an</strong><br />

only be issued by certain institutions like governments, comp<strong>an</strong>ies, b<strong>an</strong>ks, special purpose<br />

vehicles, etc.. Issuing bonds is a time-consuming process which needs much more resources<br />

th<strong>an</strong> borrowing from a b<strong>an</strong>k. Therefore, it is only worthwhile for large issue sizes.<br />

Unlike stock holders, bond holders do not own a part of the issuing institution. They<br />

are rather lenders to the institution. As bonds have a maturity date with a predetermined<br />

repayment, bond price volatility is decre<strong>as</strong>ing with less remaining time to maturity. Par-<br />

ticularly investment-grade 16 bonds are therefore seen <strong>as</strong> relatively safe investments if they<br />

are held until maturity.<br />

Weaknesses of the Bond Market<br />

Bond markets are <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t component of tr<strong>an</strong>sferring <strong>an</strong>d trading credit risk. Still,<br />

they involve some weaknesses which are described below.<br />

• The bond market size is relatively small related to the overall credit risk universe<br />

accruing from fin<strong>an</strong>cial intermediation. A large fraction comes from b<strong>an</strong>ks acting <strong>as</strong><br />

lenders.<br />

• Government <strong>an</strong>d sovereign debt constitute a large fraction of the overall bond market.<br />

Thus, investors have limited possibilities to trade with corporate bonds.<br />

• The existing corporate bond market enables investors mainly to invest in large cor-<br />

porations, investment-grade rated. Due to the relatively small market, liquidity<br />

problems may arise.<br />

• The available bonds may not meet investor’s requirements, regarding for example<br />

maturity or currency, <strong>as</strong> they are issued mainly according to issuer’s needs.<br />

• Investors in the bond market c<strong>an</strong>not engage in structured credit risk exposure. 17<br />

The weaknesses of the bond markets, the incre<strong>as</strong>ing interest in credit risk from fixed<br />

income investors <strong>an</strong>d the b<strong>an</strong>ks’ efforts to trade credit risk have been vital for the evolution<br />

of credit derivatives <strong>an</strong>d securitisations, which are described in the following sections.<br />

2.3 <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives<br />

2.3.1 Definition <strong>an</strong>d Functionality<br />

At first, we give a general definition of a derivative security: ”A derivative security, or<br />

contingent claim, is a fin<strong>an</strong>cial contract whose value at expiration date T (more briefly,<br />

expiry) is determined exactly by the price (or prices within a prespecified time-interval)<br />

16 For more information regarding ratings, we refer to the Rating-paragraph in this section.<br />

17 See [D<strong>as</strong>06], pp. 803-804.<br />

10


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

of the underlying fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>sets (or instruments) at time T (within the time interval<br />

[0, T ]).” 18<br />

[D<strong>as</strong>06] defines credit derivatives <strong>as</strong> a cl<strong>as</strong>s of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instrument, whose value ”is<br />

derived from <strong>an</strong> underlying market value driven by the credit risk of private or government<br />

entities other th<strong>an</strong> the counterparties to the credit derivative tr<strong>an</strong>saction itself.” 19<br />

A credit derivative is a bilateral fin<strong>an</strong>cial contract which allows to separate <strong>an</strong>d isolate<br />

credit risk related to a credit-sensitive underlying <strong>as</strong>set, <strong>an</strong>d thus facilitates the trading of<br />

credit risk. This leads to a greater efficiency in the pricing <strong>an</strong>d distribution of credit risk<br />

among market particip<strong>an</strong>ts, who are now able to better m<strong>an</strong>age it by hedging, tr<strong>an</strong>sferring<br />

or replicating it.<br />

Figure 2.1 shows the b<strong>as</strong>ic structure of a credit derivative.<br />

Figure 2.1: B<strong>as</strong>ic structure of a credit derivative contract<br />

During the term of the credit derivative contract, the protection buyer or risk seller<br />

makes one or several premium payments to the protection seller or risk buyer. In return,<br />

the latter h<strong>as</strong> to make a conditional payment to the protection buyer if a credit event<br />

occurs during the lifetime of the derivative. A credit event is characterised with respect to a<br />

reference entity <strong>an</strong>d the reference obligations, which c<strong>an</strong> be <strong>an</strong>y fin<strong>an</strong>cial instrument issued<br />

by the reference entity <strong>an</strong>d exposed to credit risk, such <strong>as</strong> a lo<strong>an</strong>, a bond or a portfolio<br />

of lo<strong>an</strong>s or bonds. The possible credit events might include b<strong>an</strong>kruptcy, deterioration of<br />

credit quality or ch<strong>an</strong>ges of the credit spread. The contract terminates either at maturity<br />

or if a credit event h<strong>as</strong> occurred. Apart from the conditional payment, a credit derivative<br />

c<strong>an</strong> oblige the protection seller to other payments. For simplicity re<strong>as</strong>ons, we will use the<br />

terms reference entity <strong>an</strong>d reference obligation synonymously, <strong>as</strong> most authors also do not<br />

differentiate between the terms.<br />

18 See [BK04], p. 2.<br />

19 See [D<strong>as</strong>06], p. 669.<br />

11


2.3.2 Cl<strong>as</strong>sification according to Risk Category<br />

CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

<strong>Credit</strong> derivative contracts c<strong>an</strong> be cl<strong>as</strong>sified according to different risks they cover. Figure<br />

2.2 gives <strong>an</strong> overview.<br />

Figure 2.2: Risks covered by credit derivatives<br />

There are credit derivatives that are solely linked to default events. The default risk<br />

c<strong>an</strong> be covered by default products, such <strong>as</strong> credit default swaps, credit default options,<br />

b<strong>as</strong>ket default swaps, n th -to-default swaps, etc..<br />

Moreover, there are derivatives that are sensitive towards ch<strong>an</strong>ges in credit quality.<br />

The credit spread risk c<strong>an</strong> be covered by spread products, such <strong>as</strong> credit spread swaps or<br />

options.<br />

Finally, there are credit derivatives that tr<strong>an</strong>sfer the total risk related to a bond.<br />

This c<strong>an</strong> be done by me<strong>an</strong>s of total return derivatives like total return swaps. All these<br />

instruments will be explained in detail in Chapter 3.<br />

We w<strong>an</strong>t to remark that – due to the complexity <strong>an</strong>d variety of credit derivative<br />

products – it is not possible to give a complete cl<strong>as</strong>sification.<br />

One c<strong>an</strong> also think of <strong>an</strong>other cl<strong>as</strong>sification scheme. <strong>Credit</strong> derivatives c<strong>an</strong> be grouped<br />

into single-name <strong>an</strong>d multi-name instruments. Single-name credit derivatives do only have<br />

one reference entity, while multi-name credit derivatives involve protection against credit<br />

events in a pool of reference entities, such <strong>as</strong> a portfolio of bonds or lo<strong>an</strong>s.<br />

2.3.3 Re<strong>as</strong>ons for the Utilisation of <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives<br />

In this section, we will point out the re<strong>as</strong>ons for the utilisation of credit derivatives. At<br />

first, we present the specific re<strong>as</strong>ons for fin<strong>an</strong>cial institutions to use credit derivatives, since<br />

these institutions build the foundation for their development <strong>an</strong>d the enormous growth of<br />

the market. Then, we will explain general re<strong>as</strong>ons for investors to participate in the credit<br />

derivatives market both <strong>as</strong> protection buyer <strong>an</strong>d <strong>as</strong> protection seller.<br />

Specific motivations for Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Institutions to operate in the <strong>Credit</strong> Deriv-<br />

atives Market<br />

As explained in Section 2.1.2, credit risk m<strong>an</strong>agement is a vital t<strong>as</strong>k for b<strong>an</strong>ks. An active<br />

credit risk m<strong>an</strong>agement h<strong>as</strong> to be in line with <strong>an</strong> overall risk m<strong>an</strong>agement strategy. It<br />

12


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

aims at m<strong>an</strong>aging exposure concentrations <strong>an</strong>d diversifying the portfolio geographically. 20<br />

Nowadays, it is not only regulation authorities that give a motivation for efficient credit<br />

risk m<strong>an</strong>agement, but also other stakeholders, such <strong>as</strong> credit rating agencies or sharehold-<br />

ers that incre<strong>as</strong>ingly focus on a b<strong>an</strong>k’s risk exposure, risk m<strong>an</strong>agement <strong>an</strong>d capital use.<br />

Hence, a fin<strong>an</strong>cial institution h<strong>as</strong> strong incentives to reduce its credit risk which c<strong>an</strong> be<br />

accomplished by the use of credit derivatives. That way, a b<strong>an</strong>k c<strong>an</strong> m<strong>an</strong>age its capital<br />

<strong>an</strong>d reach both <strong>an</strong> economic <strong>an</strong>d a regulatory capital relief. Economic capital is freed up,<br />

if the credit derivative contract presents <strong>an</strong> effective hedge against a position held in the<br />

portfolio. Regulatory capital c<strong>an</strong> be relieved by the utilisation of derivative products if<br />

credit risk exposure c<strong>an</strong> be reduced according to regulatory rules. 21 This w<strong>as</strong> one of the<br />

main drivers for the enormously growing credit derivatives market.<br />

The use of credit derivatives to m<strong>an</strong>age their credit risk exposure involves several<br />

adv<strong>an</strong>tages for fin<strong>an</strong>cial institutions.<br />

• They c<strong>an</strong> use their capital more efficiently. Thus, they have more flexibility entering<br />

new risk-bearing activities. At the same time, their utilisation enables b<strong>an</strong>ks to<br />

maintain client relationships, <strong>as</strong> credit derivatives constitute <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>onymous <strong>an</strong>d<br />

confidential way to m<strong>an</strong>age credit risk exposure.<br />

• In general, using credit derivatives entails lower legal or setup costs th<strong>an</strong> sales <strong>an</strong>d<br />

securitisation of lo<strong>an</strong>s.<br />

• The use of derivative products to reduce the credit risk exposure c<strong>an</strong> be more tax<br />

efficient th<strong>an</strong> securitisation of lo<strong>an</strong>s.<br />

• Moreover, it helps b<strong>an</strong>ks to improve the m<strong>an</strong>agement of their credit portfolio <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

portfolio diversification. On the one h<strong>an</strong>d, b<strong>an</strong>ks c<strong>an</strong> act <strong>as</strong> protection buyers, <strong>an</strong>d<br />

thus m<strong>an</strong>aging their credit portfolio <strong>an</strong>d accomplish capital relief. On the other h<strong>an</strong>d,<br />

b<strong>an</strong>ks c<strong>an</strong> act <strong>as</strong> protection sellers, also for re<strong>as</strong>ons of portfolio m<strong>an</strong>agement but also<br />

for diversification <strong>an</strong>d yield enh<strong>an</strong>cement re<strong>as</strong>ons. That way, b<strong>an</strong>ks c<strong>an</strong> diversify<br />

their portfolio by buying credit risk from other regions or industries <strong>an</strong>d they c<strong>an</strong><br />

acquire exposure to certain borrowers that they otherwise hardly could acquire.<br />

Thus, selling protection c<strong>an</strong> be viewed <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> alternative to lo<strong>an</strong> origination. 22<br />

This paragraph presented the specific re<strong>as</strong>ons for fin<strong>an</strong>cial institutions to enter into credit<br />

derivative contracts. The following paragraph will present the motivations for investors,<br />

in general, to participate in the credit derivatives market.<br />

Motivation for Investors to participate in the <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives Market<br />

There are various re<strong>as</strong>ons for investors to participate in the credit derivatives market. We<br />

c<strong>an</strong> differentiate between particip<strong>an</strong>ts who act <strong>as</strong> protection buyers or <strong>as</strong> protection sellers.<br />

In the following, we describe re<strong>as</strong>ons for acting <strong>as</strong> protection buyers.<br />

20 See [Bom05], pp. 29-30, [Fit05], pp. 7-8.<br />

21 The terms economic <strong>an</strong>d regulatory capital are explained in Section 2.1.2.<br />

22 See [D<strong>as</strong>06], p. 671, [Bom05], p. 31, 34, 39, [Deu04], p. 29.<br />

13


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

• Buying protection allows investors to mimic a short selling of bonds, particularly of<br />

corporate bonds, if they expect <strong>an</strong> issuer’s credit quality to deteriorate <strong>an</strong>d hence,<br />

bond prices to fall. In general, short selling strategies c<strong>an</strong> be implemented in highly<br />

liquid fin<strong>an</strong>cial markets, such <strong>as</strong> the market for US Tre<strong>as</strong>ury securities. But this<br />

might prove difficult for corporate debt market. By entering into a credit derivative<br />

contract, the investor c<strong>an</strong> express its view about the future credit quality of the<br />

reference entity <strong>an</strong>d hence profit from corresponding developments.<br />

• Buying protection in the credit derivatives market against the default of major pur-<br />

ch<strong>as</strong>ers or suppliers allow corporations to m<strong>an</strong>age their credit risk exposure. Thus,<br />

they c<strong>an</strong> concentrate on their core business <strong>an</strong>d might even be able to strengthen <strong>an</strong>d<br />

to extend their market position, for example by gr<strong>an</strong>ting more vendor fin<strong>an</strong>cing. 23<br />

As we have seen, there are m<strong>an</strong>y re<strong>as</strong>ons for b<strong>an</strong>ks <strong>an</strong>d other market particip<strong>an</strong>ts to<br />

buy protection in the credit derivatives market. There are also other market particip<strong>an</strong>ts<br />

for whom it is appealing to act <strong>as</strong> protection sellers for numerous re<strong>as</strong>ons, which are<br />

presented below.<br />

• Generally, credit derivatives are ”unfunded” instruments, which me<strong>an</strong>s that, at in-<br />

ception, no capital h<strong>as</strong> to be invested. Usually, there exists <strong>an</strong> agreement that the<br />

protection buyer makes (periodic) payments to the protection seller. If no credit<br />

event occurs <strong>an</strong>d if the counterparty remains solvent, the protection seller receives<br />

a guar<strong>an</strong>teed, regular income stream during the term of the derivative without ini-<br />

tially investing <strong>an</strong>y capital. In contr<strong>as</strong>t, creating a similar income stream from a<br />

bond would involve the purch<strong>as</strong>e of the bond which is a considerable investment.<br />

Therefore, acting <strong>as</strong> protection seller allows investors to effectively leverage their<br />

credit risk exposure. This kind of investing is particularly interesting for investors<br />

with high funding costs, which could me<strong>an</strong> that buying the bond is more expen-<br />

sive th<strong>an</strong> the income generated from the bond <strong>an</strong>d consequently, a bond investment<br />

would be unattractive.<br />

• Some investors, such <strong>as</strong> insur<strong>an</strong>ce comp<strong>an</strong>ies, consider credit risk to be uncorrelated<br />

with other risk positions in their portfolio. Therefore, they act <strong>as</strong> protections sellers<br />

in order to add value to their portfolio while diversifying their risks.<br />

• Traditional institutional investors <strong>an</strong>d <strong>as</strong>set m<strong>an</strong>agers are generally not able to invest<br />

in lo<strong>an</strong> markets. If a certain borrower does not issue bonds but only borrows from<br />

b<strong>an</strong>ks, selling protection against this reference entity enables investors to synthesise<br />

a long position in that borrower’s debt, <strong>an</strong>d thus synthesise <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set that would<br />

otherwise not be available to them. 24<br />

Within the credit derivatives market, there are different types of market particip<strong>an</strong>ts:<br />

Hedgers or investors with a dem<strong>an</strong>d for risk m<strong>an</strong>agement or for tailored products, specu-<br />

lators <strong>an</strong>d arbitrageurs.<br />

<strong>Credit</strong> derivatives allow to isolate credit risk from various other types of risks embedded<br />

in debt instruments, <strong>an</strong>d then tr<strong>an</strong>sfer it from one counterparty to <strong>an</strong>other. They c<strong>an</strong> be<br />

23 See [D<strong>as</strong>06], p. 671, [Bom05], pp. 37-38.<br />

24 See [D<strong>as</strong>06], p. 671, [Bom05], pp. 35-36 <strong>an</strong>d [BR04], p. 16.<br />

14


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

tailored for the specific needs of a market particip<strong>an</strong>t. Thus, they help investors to better<br />

m<strong>an</strong>age their credit risk exposure. They also allow for synthesising <strong>as</strong>sets that would not<br />

be available for certain investors or that even do not exist.<br />

<strong>Credit</strong> derivatives are also used for the purpose of speculation. A market particip<strong>an</strong>t<br />

does not need to have <strong>an</strong> exposure to a debt instrument to enter into a credit derivative<br />

contract. <strong>Credit</strong> derivatives c<strong>an</strong> rather be used to express one’s opinion about future<br />

credit quality of a reference entity, <strong>an</strong>d that way to fin<strong>an</strong>cially participate in its ch<strong>an</strong>ges<br />

by trading these instruments. For the investor, the underlying itself is irrelev<strong>an</strong>t. He is<br />

only interested in generating a profit from trading.<br />

Another kind of market particip<strong>an</strong>t is <strong>an</strong> arbitrageur, who tries to benefit from pricing<br />

differences in two or more markets.<br />

2.3.4 Ch<strong>an</strong>ces <strong>an</strong>d Risks related to <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives Markets<br />

The credit derivatives markets incorporate both ch<strong>an</strong>ces <strong>an</strong>d risks, which are described in<br />

this section.<br />

Ch<strong>an</strong>ces related to <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives Markets<br />

On a microeconomic level, credit derivatives are instruments for credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer, partly<br />

comparable to traditional instruments for credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer such <strong>as</strong> lo<strong>an</strong> sale or credit<br />

insur<strong>an</strong>ce. The characteristics of the derivatives <strong>an</strong>d their possible applications, however,<br />

go far beyond those of the traditional instruments such <strong>as</strong> lo<strong>an</strong> sales <strong>an</strong>d credit insur<strong>an</strong>ce.<br />

<strong>Credit</strong> derivatives allow b<strong>an</strong>ks to isolate <strong>an</strong>d to trade credit risks <strong>as</strong> well <strong>as</strong> to dynamically<br />

adjust their credit risks, <strong>an</strong>d thus optimising their risk profile.<br />

On a macroeconomic level, the utilisation of credit derivatives c<strong>an</strong> contribute to im-<br />

prove the overall risk allocation within fin<strong>an</strong>cial systems, which c<strong>an</strong> be accomplished in the<br />

following ways: First, b<strong>an</strong>ks are enabled to perform risk m<strong>an</strong>agement in a more flexible<br />

<strong>an</strong>d efficient way. Second, the incre<strong>as</strong>ed trading activities improve the tr<strong>an</strong>sparency <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the quality of the pricing. Third, credit risk is distributed more efficiently. Hence, the<br />

aggregated risk within a national economy is reduced <strong>an</strong>d market crises c<strong>an</strong> be better ab-<br />

sorbed <strong>as</strong> risks <strong>an</strong>d possibly implied damages are less concentrated. All in all, the stability<br />

of the fin<strong>an</strong>cial system c<strong>an</strong> be incre<strong>as</strong>ed. 25<br />

Risks related to <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives Markets<br />

We examine the risks induced by credit derivative contracts. Table 2.1 gives <strong>an</strong> overview<br />

on the possible risks inherent in credit derivatives markets.<br />

The risks related to the credit derivatives markets c<strong>an</strong> be cl<strong>as</strong>sified into two groups:<br />

Risks on contract level <strong>an</strong>d risks on market level. At first, we explain the risks on contract<br />

level.<br />

• Counterparty risk – risk that one of the counterparties (protection seller or buyer)<br />

is unable to fulfil its contractual obligations.<br />

25 See [DBR04], pp. 1-3 <strong>an</strong>d [Deu04], pp. 36-37.<br />

15


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

Risks on contract level Risks on market level<br />

Counterparty risk Liquidity risk<br />

B<strong>as</strong>is risk Risk of high market concentration<br />

Legal risk/documentation risk Risk of systematic mispricing<br />

Operational risk Agency risk<br />

Model risk Risk of regulatory arbitrage<br />

Risk of market intr<strong>an</strong>sparency<br />

Table 2.1: Risks in credit derivatives markets<br />

• B<strong>as</strong>is risk – risk of a potential loss that could arise from <strong>an</strong> imperfect hedge, for<br />

example, hedging the credit risk exposure of one reference entity with <strong>an</strong>other highly<br />

correlated, but different reference entity.<br />

• Legal risk – risk of potential losses that could arise from not clearly specified contract<br />

conditions or from unforeseen future events. Furthermore, they c<strong>an</strong> arise from rights<br />

that are not enforceable. The documentation risk c<strong>an</strong> be viewed <strong>as</strong> part of the legal<br />

risk. It is the risk of different notions of a credit event according to the contract.<br />

The uniqueness of the contract terms is vital for the stability of the fin<strong>an</strong>cial system.<br />

Therefore, the International Swaps <strong>an</strong>d Derivatives Association (ISDA) developed<br />

st<strong>an</strong>dards for credit derivatives contracts, which are import<strong>an</strong>t for facilitating their<br />

trading. But the st<strong>an</strong>dards c<strong>an</strong>not exclude <strong>an</strong>y legal risk. 26<br />

• Operational risk – risk of potential losses or unrealised profits caused by the failure<br />

of the technical infr<strong>as</strong>tructure. It also involves the risk of losses resulting from<br />

inadequate or failed internal processes, people or external events.<br />

• Model risk – risk of losses caused by <strong>an</strong> under- or overestimation of the fair value<br />

of a credit derivative contract due to a wrong pricing model or driven by incorrect<br />

model parameters. 27<br />

After having seen the risks on contract level, we will discuss the risks involved in credit<br />

derivatives markets on market level.<br />

• Liquidity risk – risk of adversely affecting the market price when trading in large<br />

size.<br />

• High market concentration – This me<strong>an</strong>s that the trading of credit derivatives h<strong>as</strong><br />

been limited to a small number of market particip<strong>an</strong>ts. From the high market<br />

concentration may also arise <strong>an</strong> illusion of liquidity. A sudden withdrawal of a large<br />

market particip<strong>an</strong>t may lead to considerable price movements in the market <strong>an</strong>d to<br />

a serious liquidity risk in the short-term. 28 Furthermore, it might lead to higher<br />

tr<strong>an</strong>saction costs <strong>an</strong>d a suboptimal risk allocation within a fin<strong>an</strong>cial system. Hence,<br />

the stability of fin<strong>an</strong>cial markets could be affected. 29<br />

26 For more information about the st<strong>an</strong>dardisation process we refer to Section 2.3.6<br />

27 See [Deu04], pp. 37-44, [DBR04], pp. 6-7, [Bom05], pp. 10-15, [BIS05a], p. 140.<br />

28 This is the result from a poll conducted by Deutsche Bundesb<strong>an</strong>k in autumn 2003 (see [Deu04], p.<br />

40). Also, the FitchRatings Global <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives Survey (see [Fit05], p. 2) highlights the risk for the<br />

market liquidity in c<strong>as</strong>e of the withdrawal of <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t market-maker.<br />

29 This is considered to be relatively unrealistic. There is rather a tendency to <strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>ing number of<br />

particip<strong>an</strong>ts <strong>as</strong> more particip<strong>an</strong>ts w<strong>an</strong>t to profit from the use of credit derivatives. (See [DBR04], p. 9.)<br />

16


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

• Systematic mispricing – Models for pricing credit derivatives are in <strong>an</strong> early de-<br />

velopment stage. There is no generally accepted pricing model. Partly, the used<br />

models are insufficiently able to map complex portfolio products, which c<strong>an</strong> lead to<br />

<strong>an</strong> underestimation of the real risk, <strong>an</strong>d thus to undesirably high risk <strong>an</strong>d to a wrong<br />

allocation of resources with a disequilibrating impact on fin<strong>an</strong>cial stability.<br />

• Agency risk – In terms of occurrence probability <strong>an</strong>d expected amount of loss, protec-<br />

tion sellers are able to better evaluate the tr<strong>an</strong>sferred credit risk th<strong>an</strong> the protection<br />

buyers. Therefore, there is a d<strong>an</strong>ger that the protection sellers only sell bad risks.<br />

This phenomenon is also known <strong>as</strong> adverse selection. A further agency problem may<br />

accrue from the fact that, after the credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer, the protection buyer h<strong>as</strong><br />

little incentive to monitor the borrower in order to influence the occurrence proba-<br />

bility <strong>an</strong>d expected amount of loss in c<strong>as</strong>e of default. At the gr<strong>an</strong>ting of a credit, a<br />

b<strong>an</strong>k might be even less careful, knowing that she will hedge the credit risk. This<br />

phenomenon is known <strong>as</strong> moral hazard. 30<br />

• Regulatory arbitrage – B<strong>an</strong>ks effectively hedge against certain positions in their port-<br />

folio by tr<strong>an</strong>sferring the inherent credit risk to counterparties. This is particularly<br />

done with positions requiring more regulatory th<strong>an</strong> economic capital. Thus, regula-<br />

tory capital relief is accomplished, while credit risk exposure may then be <strong>as</strong>sumed<br />

by less regulated market particip<strong>an</strong>ts. This could result in <strong>an</strong> inefficient risk al-<br />

location <strong>as</strong> risk is systematically taken over by market particip<strong>an</strong>ts that have less<br />

knowledge <strong>an</strong>d experience in dealing with risks. Furthermore, they might have a<br />

smaller capital cushion to absorb unexpected losses <strong>as</strong> they are not regulated. Reg-<br />

ulatory arbitrage exploits inconsistencies in capital regulation <strong>an</strong>d is one of the main<br />

re<strong>as</strong>ons for continually improving capital requirements. 31 32<br />

• Market intr<strong>an</strong>sparency – As the credit derivatives market is <strong>an</strong> over-the-counter<br />

(OTC) market, there is <strong>an</strong> information deficiency. Information regarding the trading<br />

volume of credit derivatives often h<strong>as</strong> been b<strong>as</strong>ed on estimations <strong>an</strong>d polls among<br />

market particip<strong>an</strong>ts, but not on disclosure requirements. This insufficient tr<strong>an</strong>s-<br />

parency in the market <strong>an</strong>d the lack of insight into firm level exposures <strong>an</strong>d positions<br />

h<strong>as</strong> prevented <strong>an</strong> adequate <strong>as</strong>sessment of the risk allocation within a national econ-<br />

omy. Hence, the possibility to early identify potential systemic risks threatening the<br />

stability of the fin<strong>an</strong>cial system is limited. There are efforts to improve the tr<strong>an</strong>s-<br />

parency <strong>an</strong>d disclosure requirements with respect to fin<strong>an</strong>cial institutions. Not all<br />

market particip<strong>an</strong>ts, however, c<strong>an</strong> be included. 33<br />

To conclude, there are several risks in credit derivative markets that c<strong>an</strong> potentially<br />

threaten the stability of fin<strong>an</strong>cial markets. They are particularly import<strong>an</strong>t until the<br />

market is mature. At this stage, some risks have already been reduced successfully, for<br />

30<br />

This risk is more likely to be of theoretical nature. In practice, there are several mech<strong>an</strong>isms that<br />

prevent these risks such <strong>as</strong> reputation effects <strong>an</strong>d retention. (See [DBR04], p. 13, [Deu04], p. 42.)<br />

31<br />

Regulatory arbitrage is to be prevented through the implementation of B<strong>as</strong>el II <strong>as</strong> regulatory capital<br />

is calculated by taking into account the borrower’s <strong>an</strong>d the counterparty’s credit quality.<br />

32<br />

Deutsche Bundesb<strong>an</strong>k considers risk for the stability of fin<strong>an</strong>cial markets accruing from regulatory<br />

arbitrage not to be pivotal. (See [Deu04], p. 41.)<br />

33<br />

See [Deu04], p. 37-45, [DBR04], pp. 1-14, [BOW03], p. 211, [Fit05], pp. 2-3.<br />

17


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

example the documentation risk, or c<strong>an</strong> be viewed <strong>as</strong> being primarily of theoretical interest,<br />

such <strong>as</strong> agency problems. Therefore, credit derivatives contribute today to a better risk<br />

m<strong>an</strong>agement. By further reducing the described risks in the future, fin<strong>an</strong>cial markets c<strong>an</strong><br />

incre<strong>as</strong>ingly benefit from credit derivatives <strong>an</strong>d gain stability in the long term.<br />

2.3.5 Tr<strong>an</strong>saction Costs<br />

<strong>Credit</strong> derivatives involve lower tr<strong>an</strong>saction costs th<strong>an</strong> replicating the derivative contract<br />

with c<strong>as</strong>h instruments. Furthermore, tr<strong>an</strong>saction costs have been reduced due to the<br />

narrowing of the bid-<strong>as</strong>k spreads. 34<br />

2.3.6 Market<br />

The credit derivatives market h<strong>as</strong> grown at <strong>an</strong> enormous rate over recent years. In this<br />

section, we provide <strong>an</strong> overview on the evolution of the market <strong>an</strong>d its size. Furthermore,<br />

we have a closer look at the market particip<strong>an</strong>ts, also differentiating between protection<br />

sellers <strong>an</strong>d protection buyers. Finally, we will consider the market size by instrument, by<br />

reference entity <strong>an</strong>d by credit quality.<br />

As already mentioned, credit derivatives are mostly OTC-traded. Therefore, it is<br />

difficult to <strong>an</strong>alyse the market. There are a few surveys of market particip<strong>an</strong>ts, conducted<br />

for example by FitchRatings 35 or British B<strong>an</strong>kers’ Association (BBA) 36 , that publicly<br />

provide information with respect to volume, market particip<strong>an</strong>ts or reference entities.<br />

These surveys entail some problems that have to be taken into account when using <strong>an</strong>d<br />

interpreting the results: Only a limited number of market particip<strong>an</strong>ts c<strong>an</strong> be surveyed.<br />

Not all of those will <strong>an</strong>swer the survey, some will <strong>an</strong>swer it in a bad quality. Moreover, the<br />

stated notional amounts overestimate the effective net exposure of the credit derivatives<br />

contracts since potential recovery rates <strong>as</strong> well <strong>as</strong> netting <strong>an</strong>d collateralisation are not<br />

considered. 37 38<br />

Evolution <strong>an</strong>d Size<br />

Figure 2.3 shows the development of the global credit derivatives market with respect to<br />

the total notional amount. 39 Here, we w<strong>an</strong>t to remark that the problems related to such<br />

surveys <strong>an</strong>d pointed out earlier, should be borne in mind.<br />

FitchRatings presents similar results with respect to market size in 2004. According<br />

to FitchRatings, the market exp<strong>an</strong>ded to USD 5,290 (= 5.290 · 10 12 ) billion of outst<strong>an</strong>ding<br />

contracts on a total notional amounts b<strong>as</strong>is in 2004. If c<strong>as</strong>h CDOs are included, the market<br />

even exp<strong>an</strong>ded to USD 5,449 billion. 40<br />

34<br />

See [Bom05], p. 5 <strong>an</strong>d [Deu04b], p. 47.<br />

35<br />

See [Fit05].<br />

36<br />

See [Bri04].<br />

37<br />

The FitchRatings survey ([Fit05]) incorporates 120 fin<strong>an</strong>cial institutions (73 b<strong>an</strong>ks <strong>an</strong>d broker dealers,<br />

39 insur<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d re-insur<strong>an</strong>ce comp<strong>an</strong>ies, eight fin<strong>an</strong>cial guar<strong>an</strong>tors) from all over the world. So it covers all<br />

major institutions with exception of one big broker-dealer. The BBA study ([Bri04]) involves 30 institutions<br />

from m<strong>an</strong>y different countries, which are key player in the credit derivatives market.<br />

38<br />

Netting <strong>an</strong>d collateralisation are discussed at the end of Section 2.3.6.<br />

39 The data is taken from [Bri04], p. 5.<br />

40 See [Fit05], p. 1 <strong>an</strong>d underlying data file.<br />

18


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

Figure 2.3: Global credit derivatives market (in USD billions, excluding <strong>as</strong>set swaps)<br />

The credit derivatives market shows <strong>an</strong> impressing growth. Its size is still small com-<br />

pared to other derivatives markets. Also in other respects, such <strong>as</strong> liquidity, tr<strong>an</strong>sparency,<br />

st<strong>an</strong>dardisation <strong>an</strong>d number of market particip<strong>an</strong>ts, the credit derivatives market lags<br />

behind other derivatives markets. <strong>Credit</strong> derivatives, however, are the worldwide f<strong>as</strong>test<br />

growing derivative product <strong>an</strong>d one of the f<strong>as</strong>test growing securities in the global securities<br />

market. 41<br />

Market Particip<strong>an</strong>ts<br />

Large commercial <strong>an</strong>d investment b<strong>an</strong>ks, securities houses, insur<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d re-insur<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

comp<strong>an</strong>ies, fin<strong>an</strong>cial guar<strong>an</strong>tors, <strong>an</strong>d hedge funds are the main market particip<strong>an</strong>ts in the<br />

credit derivatives market. There are still some more particip<strong>an</strong>ts who only contribute<br />

a small share to the overall market such <strong>as</strong> <strong>as</strong>set m<strong>an</strong>agers, high-net-worth individuals,<br />

special purpose vehicles (SPV) 42 , <strong>an</strong>d other corporates. 43<br />

The global b<strong>an</strong>king industry still turns out to be a signific<strong>an</strong>t buyer of protection, with<br />

a net position 44 of USD 427 billion. Hence, this amount is tr<strong>an</strong>sferred outside the b<strong>an</strong>king<br />

industry to third parties, such <strong>as</strong> hedge funds <strong>an</strong>d insur<strong>an</strong>ce comp<strong>an</strong>ies. 45<br />

Analysing the b<strong>an</strong>king industry in more detail, we detect considerable regional dif-<br />

ferences. All reported regions acted <strong>as</strong> net protection buyers in 2004. Europe<strong>an</strong> b<strong>an</strong>ks<br />

bought USD 294 billion of protection, North Americ<strong>an</strong> b<strong>an</strong>ks <strong>an</strong>d broker-dealers bought<br />

USD 123 billion, <strong>an</strong>d Australi<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d Asi<strong>an</strong> b<strong>an</strong>ks bought USD 10 billion. Within the<br />

41 See [Bom05], p. 18, [BR04], p. 16, [Fit05], p. 11.<br />

42 More information regarding SPVs c<strong>an</strong> be found in Section 2.4.1.<br />

43 See [Bri04], p. 5, [Fit05], pp. 1-3, [Bom05], p. 23, [BIS05a], pp. 22-23.<br />

44 The net position is the difference between the amount that w<strong>as</strong> gross sold <strong>an</strong>d the amount that w<strong>as</strong><br />

gross bought. Thus, if the amount that w<strong>as</strong> gross bought exceeds the amount that w<strong>as</strong> gross sold, then<br />

the market particip<strong>an</strong>t is a net protection buyer, <strong>an</strong>d vice versa.<br />

45 See [Fit05], p. 1.<br />

19


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

Europe<strong>an</strong> b<strong>an</strong>ks, Germ<strong>an</strong>y had by far the smallest net share with approximately USD 15<br />

billion. In 2003, Germ<strong>an</strong>y even w<strong>as</strong> a net protection seller. 46<br />

There are smaller regional b<strong>an</strong>ks within the b<strong>an</strong>king sector acting <strong>as</strong> protection sellers,<br />

since they consider credit derivatives <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> alternative to enh<strong>an</strong>ce the yield on their capital,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d they view them <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> alternative or additional me<strong>an</strong>s of originating lo<strong>an</strong>s. 47<br />

Insur<strong>an</strong>ce, re-insur<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d fin<strong>an</strong>cial guar<strong>an</strong>tors mainly act <strong>as</strong> protection sellers. The<br />

overall net position amounts to USD 556 billion, thereof USD 319 billion taken over by<br />

the insur<strong>an</strong>ce sector. The insur<strong>an</strong>ce industry considers protection selling <strong>as</strong> profitable<br />

for several re<strong>as</strong>ons: Corporate default is viewed <strong>as</strong> being nearly uncorrelated with the<br />

risks in their portfolio. Thus, by selling protection, both portfolio diversification <strong>an</strong>d<br />

yield enh<strong>an</strong>cement of capital c<strong>an</strong> be achieved. Fin<strong>an</strong>cial strength of insur<strong>an</strong>ce comp<strong>an</strong>ies<br />

makes them appealing counterparties for institutions looking for protection buying, <strong>as</strong><br />

counterparty risk is very small. 48<br />

The difference of approximately USD 130 billion is held by market particip<strong>an</strong>ts that<br />

are not covered by the survey, such <strong>as</strong> <strong>as</strong>set m<strong>an</strong>agers or hedge funds. 49<br />

Hedge funds have emerged <strong>as</strong> players in the credit derivatives market for both protec-<br />

tion buying <strong>an</strong>d selling. They are estimated to have a share of approximately 25%-30% of<br />

the overall credit derivatives trading volume. Hedge funds have become more <strong>an</strong>d more<br />

import<strong>an</strong>t to fin<strong>an</strong>cial markets, <strong>as</strong> they contribute to reduce or even to eliminate mis-<br />

pricing of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments by pursuing arbitrage opportunities. Probably the most<br />

import<strong>an</strong>t characteristic of hedge funds is their ability to inject signific<strong>an</strong>t liquidity into<br />

fin<strong>an</strong>cial markets not only in periods of normal market conditions but also – particularly<br />

more import<strong>an</strong>t – in periods of stress. As they are largely exempted from regulation <strong>an</strong>d<br />

able to e<strong>as</strong>ily implement investment strategies (often realised by taking short positions to<br />

a great extent), they c<strong>an</strong> supply the market more e<strong>as</strong>ily <strong>an</strong>d effectively with liquidity th<strong>an</strong><br />

other fin<strong>an</strong>cial institutions. 50<br />

Table 2.2 is taken from [Bri04] <strong>an</strong>d it gives <strong>an</strong> overview on the market shares of main<br />

buyers <strong>an</strong>d sellers of protection for 2003 <strong>an</strong>d forec<strong>as</strong>ts the shares for 2006.<br />

Protection Buyer 2003 2006e<br />

B<strong>an</strong>ks 51% 43%<br />

Securities Houses 16% 15%<br />

Hedge Funds 16% 17%<br />

Protection Seller 2003 2006e<br />

B<strong>an</strong>ks 38% 34%<br />

Insur<strong>an</strong>ce Comp<strong>an</strong>ies 20% 21%<br />

Securities Houses 16% 14%<br />

Hedge Funds 15% 15%<br />

Table 2.2: Market shares of main protection buyers <strong>an</strong>d sellers<br />

From the table, we c<strong>an</strong> see a forec<strong>as</strong>ted declining share of b<strong>an</strong>ks acting both <strong>as</strong> pro-<br />

tection sellers <strong>an</strong>d buyers. The other shares are forec<strong>as</strong>ted to remain relatively stable.<br />

46<br />

See [Fit05], pp. 4-6, [Fit04], p. 4.<br />

47<br />

See [Fit05], p. 6, [Bom05], p. 24.<br />

48<br />

See [Fit05], p. 2,6, [Bom05], p. 24.<br />

49<br />

See [Fit05], p. 2.<br />

50<br />

See [Bri04], p. 5, [Fit05], p. 7, [Gre05], p. 5.<br />

20


Market Breakdown<br />

CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

The credit derivatives market c<strong>an</strong> be cl<strong>as</strong>sified according to different <strong>as</strong>pects, such <strong>as</strong><br />

instrument type, reference entity, credit quality. In this section, we give <strong>an</strong> overview on<br />

the market in these <strong>as</strong>pects.<br />

By Instrument From a global perspective, single name CDS dominate the market.<br />

With gross sold USD 3,626 billion in 2004, they account for two-third of all gross sold<br />

credit derivatives positions. Compared to 2003, they grew by 88%. Portfolio products<br />

represent the second largest share of credit derivatives with gross sold USD 1,119 billion.<br />

This category contains single tr<strong>an</strong>che CDOs, n th -to-default swaps, etc.. The third largest<br />

gross sold position is a category denoted ”Other” with gross sold USD 469 billion, which<br />

contains traded CDS indices 51 , such <strong>as</strong> DJ iTraxx Europe CDS index <strong>an</strong>d the DJ North<br />

Americ<strong>an</strong> High-Yield CDS index, <strong>as</strong> well <strong>as</strong> index-related products. During 2004 it grew<br />

by even 425%. In FitchRating’s opinion, it is supposed to continue its rapid growth in the<br />

future, <strong>as</strong> the indices represent a st<strong>an</strong>dard benchmark by which credit risk c<strong>an</strong> be hedged<br />

<strong>an</strong>d traded. In terms of gross sold positions follow the categories c<strong>as</strong>h CDOs, total return<br />

swaps <strong>an</strong>d credit linked notes. In 2003, the product order with respect to size w<strong>as</strong> the<br />

same. 52 53<br />

Figure 2.4 shows the market breakdown in 2004, which is described above. 54<br />

Figure 2.4: Market shares of credit derivatives products<br />

According to the BBA study, CDS had a market share of 53% in 2003, which is<br />

forec<strong>as</strong>ted to decline to approximately 46% in 2006. The portfolio/synthetic CDOs had<br />

a market share of 16% in 2003, which supposed to remain stable. Indices had a share of<br />

11% in 2003 <strong>an</strong>d are supposed to have a share of 20% in 2006. <strong>Credit</strong> linked notes, total<br />

return swaps, b<strong>as</strong>ket products <strong>an</strong>d credit spread products had a share of smaller th<strong>an</strong> 8%<br />

in 2003. The forec<strong>as</strong>ts also see them remaining smaller th<strong>an</strong> 8% in 2006. 55<br />

51 For more information regarding CDS indices we refer to Section 3.9.<br />

52 See [Fit05], pp. 1-4, [Fit04], p. 2-3.<br />

53 The study also gives more insight into breakdown by instruments within the b<strong>an</strong>king, insur<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d<br />

fin<strong>an</strong>cial guar<strong>an</strong>tors sector. We refer the interested reader to [Fit05].<br />

54 See [Fit05], pp. 1-4.<br />

55 See [Bri04], p. 6. The numbers are adjusted to the needs of the thesis, <strong>as</strong> our notion of credit derivatives<br />

does not comprise <strong>as</strong>set swaps or equity linked products in accord<strong>an</strong>ce with most of the literature.<br />

21


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

By Reference Entity The breakdown of reference entities in 2004 in a global consid-<br />

eration is presented in Figure 2.5. 56<br />

Figure 2.5: Market shares of reference entities<br />

Corporates have a domin<strong>an</strong>t share of 62% of gross sold positions in 2004. They are<br />

followed by fin<strong>an</strong>cials with 14%, sovereigns only have a share of 6%. Compared to 2003, the<br />

shares remained relatively stable. The portfolio breakdown reveals the needs of fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

institutions to meet the funding dem<strong>an</strong>ds of large corporate customers, while reducing<br />

large corporate exposures. 57 The share of sovereign entities dramatically decre<strong>as</strong>ed since<br />

1996, from <strong>an</strong> estimated share of 54%. 58<br />

By <strong>Credit</strong> Quality The global credit derivatives exposures in 2004 by rating is given<br />

in Figure 2.6. 59<br />

Figure 2.6: Reference entities by credit rating<br />

56 The data is taken from [Fit05].<br />

57 See [Fit05], p. 8, [Fit04].<br />

58 See [Bri04], p. 6. The document does not give more insight into the breakdown by reference entity.<br />

59 The data is taken from [Fit05].<br />

22


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

Within the recent years, a shift in credit quality of the reference entities h<strong>as</strong> taken<br />

place. While in 2002 the share of AAA-rated reference entities w<strong>as</strong> 22%, it decre<strong>as</strong>ed to<br />

14% in 2004. A similar reduction on a relative b<strong>as</strong>is c<strong>an</strong> be observed for AA- <strong>an</strong>d A-rated<br />

reference entities. In contr<strong>as</strong>t, the share of BBB-rated reference entities incre<strong>as</strong>ed from<br />

28% in 2002 to 32% in 2004. The share of below investment-grade rated reference entities<br />

incre<strong>as</strong>ed from 8% in 2002 to 24% in 2004. These developments have various re<strong>as</strong>ons:<br />

Partly, the shift in the high-rated reference entities c<strong>an</strong> be explained by a negative ratings<br />

migration. But there is also a ch<strong>an</strong>ge in investors’ needs <strong>an</strong>d in the structure of the market<br />

particip<strong>an</strong>ts. There is a growing dem<strong>an</strong>d for high-yield CDS indices <strong>an</strong>d index products,<br />

which is driven to a large extent by hedge funds. They are looking for <strong>an</strong> alternative way<br />

to trade credit risk, with a focussed interest in high-yield <strong>as</strong>sets. 60<br />

St<strong>an</strong>dardisation of Documentation<br />

<strong>Credit</strong> derivatives are legally binding contracts between two counterparties, which may<br />

involve legal risk 61 <strong>an</strong>d enormous tr<strong>an</strong>saction costs (including setup, negotiation <strong>an</strong>d ad-<br />

ministration costs), if every contract is negotiated individually. The counterparties have<br />

to agree upon key items, such <strong>as</strong> maturity, premium, reference entity, credit event, etc.. 62<br />

In order to st<strong>an</strong>dardise the contracts <strong>an</strong>d to facilitate trading, the International Swaps<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Derivatives Association (ISDA) 63 h<strong>as</strong> pursued a steady convergence of documentation<br />

st<strong>an</strong>dards for b<strong>as</strong>ic credit derivatives contracts. In 1997, ISDA published the first set of<br />

credit derivatives documents. In 1999, the <strong>as</strong>sociation issued the ”M<strong>as</strong>ter Agreement”<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the ”<strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives Definitions”, of which a new version w<strong>as</strong> published in 2003.<br />

The former is a contract of general nature between the two counterparties on which is<br />

agreed upon before the first credit derivative contract is signed. It contains legal <strong>as</strong>pects,<br />

procedures in c<strong>as</strong>e of default of one counterparty, etc.. The latter defines key terms, such<br />

<strong>as</strong> possible credit events or possible settlement procedures. ISDA in cooperation with<br />

its members h<strong>as</strong> continuously improved these publications in order to meet the ch<strong>an</strong>ging<br />

needs of market particip<strong>an</strong>ts. 64<br />

The ISDA st<strong>an</strong>dard contract specifies all obligations <strong>an</strong>d rights of the counterparties<br />

<strong>as</strong> well <strong>as</strong> key definitions, such <strong>as</strong> reference entity, credit event <strong>an</strong>d its verification, etc. It<br />

contains some fixed core terms <strong>an</strong>d definitions, some clauses, however, are variable.<br />

Several events c<strong>an</strong> be included in the definition of a credit event, for example b<strong>an</strong>k-<br />

ruptcy, obligation acceleration, failure to pay, moratorium, restructuring. 65<br />

<strong>Credit</strong> derivatives c<strong>an</strong> be settled either physically or c<strong>as</strong>h. Physical settlement me<strong>an</strong>s<br />

that in c<strong>as</strong>e of default, the protection buyer h<strong>as</strong> to deliver the designated obligation to the<br />

protection seller in return for the par value of the reference obligation. C<strong>as</strong>h settlement<br />

me<strong>an</strong>s that if a credit event occurs, the protection seller h<strong>as</strong> to pay the difference between<br />

the par value <strong>an</strong>d the market value or the recovery value of the reference obligation to the<br />

protection buyer in c<strong>as</strong>h.<br />

60<br />

See [Fit05], p. 7, 10.<br />

61<br />

The legal risk involved in credit derivatives contracts is described in Section 2.3.4.<br />

62<br />

See [Bom05], p. 26, [Cha05], p. 57.<br />

63<br />

ISDA is <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>sociation composed of leading swap <strong>an</strong>d derivatives market particip<strong>an</strong>ts.<br />

64<br />

See [Bom05], p. 26, 286, [BR04], p. 17.<br />

65<br />

For a description of the events, we refer for example to [D<strong>as</strong>06], pp. 712-717 or to [Bom05], pp.<br />

289-290.<br />

23


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

More th<strong>an</strong> 90% of the market particip<strong>an</strong>ts use contract specifications in line with the<br />

ISDA publications. But there are still a few countries where the ISDA framework coexists<br />

with local documentation frameworks. The nearly marketwide adoption of st<strong>an</strong>dardised<br />

contracts h<strong>as</strong> led to a commoditisation of the credit derivatives market, <strong>an</strong>d thus entailed<br />

a number of adv<strong>an</strong>tages. Price discovery for these products w<strong>as</strong> improved, legal risk w<strong>as</strong><br />

reduced <strong>an</strong>d tr<strong>an</strong>saction costs were subst<strong>an</strong>tially lowered. Therefore, the st<strong>an</strong>dardisation<br />

of documentation h<strong>as</strong> considerably contributed to the rapid growth of the credit derivatives<br />

market. 66<br />

Collateralisation <strong>an</strong>d Netting<br />

With a growing credit derivatives market, the exposures of market particip<strong>an</strong>ts to each<br />

other have grown, <strong>an</strong>d therefore also the counterparty credit risk. In order to reduce the<br />

latter, the credit risk exposures are netted, i.e. if two counterparties have exposures to<br />

each other, they are offset <strong>an</strong>d only the difference is considered <strong>as</strong> exposure - the total net<br />

exposure. Often, a collateral is posted against the net exposure, which is called collateral-<br />

isation. According to the FitchRatings survey, market particip<strong>an</strong>ts have their hedge fund<br />

exposures at le<strong>as</strong>t partially collateralised. To sum up, netting <strong>an</strong>d collateralisation have<br />

helped to reduce counterparty risk. 67<br />

2.4 Securitisations<br />

2.4.1 Definition <strong>an</strong>d Functionality<br />

Securitisation denotes the tr<strong>an</strong>sfer of <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set pool into tradeable securities. In its b<strong>as</strong>ic<br />

form, a securitisation is a fin<strong>an</strong>cial tr<strong>an</strong>saction where <strong>as</strong>sets exposed to credit risk are<br />

pooled <strong>an</strong>d sold to a b<strong>an</strong>kruptcy remote <strong>an</strong>d autarkic special purpose vehicle (SPV) 68 ,<br />

which in turn refin<strong>an</strong>ces in the money or capital market by issuing tradeable securities –<br />

the <strong>as</strong>set backed securities (ABS).<br />

A subst<strong>an</strong>tial characteristic of <strong>an</strong> ABS is the separation from the b<strong>an</strong>k’s credit-worthiness<br />

of the securities’ credit-worthiness. As the <strong>as</strong>set pool serves <strong>as</strong> principal collateral, the<br />

credit-worthiness of the SPV does not play <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t role either. The ABS investors<br />

receive all c<strong>as</strong>h flows from the <strong>as</strong>set pool minus service fees. Thus, the risk <strong>an</strong>d return<br />

profile almost exclusively depends on the perform<strong>an</strong>ce of the <strong>as</strong>set portfolio.<br />

<strong>Asset</strong>s opposed to a large number of homogeneous borrowers with low default proba-<br />

bilities <strong>an</strong>d a clearly defined c<strong>as</strong>h flow structure are best suited for a securitisation.<br />

Figure 2.7 shows the b<strong>as</strong>ic structure of a securitisation. It is not intended to be<br />

exhaustive but rather gives <strong>an</strong> overview. 69<br />

The main involved parties are the originator, the SPV, the investor, the servicer, the<br />

rating agency <strong>an</strong>d the trustee.<br />

The originator generates the <strong>as</strong>set pool, for example by gr<strong>an</strong>ting lo<strong>an</strong>s to borrowers.<br />

The <strong>as</strong>set pool is tr<strong>an</strong>sferred to the SPV which is founded only for the re<strong>as</strong>on of taking over<br />

66 See [Bom05], p. 26, [Fit05], p. 3, [BIS03], p. 1, 4.<br />

67 See [Bom05], p. 27, [Fit05], p. 7.<br />

68 An exact definition of a SPV or special purpose entity (SPE) c<strong>an</strong> be found in [BIS05], p. 118.<br />

69 See [Oes04], p. 11.<br />

24


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

Figure 2.7: B<strong>as</strong>ic structure of a securitisation<br />

the <strong>as</strong>set pool or its risk, funded by the issu<strong>an</strong>ce of ABS. The originator c<strong>an</strong> often serve<br />

<strong>as</strong> servicer, who is responsible for the m<strong>an</strong>agement of the <strong>as</strong>set pool, partly including the<br />

regular collection of instalments from the borrowers, <strong>an</strong>d for regular reportings for investors<br />

<strong>an</strong>d rating agencies in return for a servicing fee. The trustee represents the investors’<br />

interests. He supervises the regularity of the SPV <strong>an</strong>d the <strong>as</strong>set pool m<strong>an</strong>agement. In<br />

addition, he also supervises the accomplishment of regular reports <strong>an</strong>d verifies losses.<br />

Sometimes, he is responsible for the payments to the investors such <strong>as</strong> shown in Figure<br />

2.7. These t<strong>as</strong>ks are often performed by <strong>an</strong> independent chartered account<strong>an</strong>t.<br />

In general, ABS are issued in different risk cl<strong>as</strong>ses, so-called tr<strong>an</strong>ches. In order to be<br />

able to place the securities in the capital market, it is necessary to get the tr<strong>an</strong>ches rated<br />

by a large rating agency. The agency regularly monitors the risk involved in the single<br />

tr<strong>an</strong>ches <strong>an</strong>d adjusts the rating if necessary.<br />

Ratings c<strong>an</strong> be influenced <strong>an</strong>d improved by so-called credit enh<strong>an</strong>cements. <strong>Credit</strong><br />

enh<strong>an</strong>cements are a distinctive feature of securitisations, unlike conventional corporate<br />

bonds, which are often unsecured. Through a credit enh<strong>an</strong>cement, a security’s or tr<strong>an</strong>che’s<br />

credit quality is raised above that of the underlying <strong>as</strong>set pool. We c<strong>an</strong> distinguish between<br />

a variety of internal <strong>an</strong>d external enh<strong>an</strong>cements that are used to limit specific risks 70<br />

accruing from a securitisation <strong>an</strong>d to decre<strong>as</strong>e the probability of default in the tr<strong>an</strong>ches.<br />

The internal enh<strong>an</strong>cements arise from the <strong>as</strong>set pool or the involved parties, examples<br />

are subordination, overcollateralisation, excess spread <strong>an</strong>d c<strong>as</strong>h reserves. External credit<br />

enh<strong>an</strong>cements are provided by a third party. Examples are fin<strong>an</strong>cial guar<strong>an</strong>tees, letters of<br />

credit, credit insur<strong>an</strong>ces <strong>an</strong>d c<strong>as</strong>h collateral accounts. 71<br />

70 These are explained in Section 2.4.4.<br />

71 For a detailed description of these credit enh<strong>an</strong>cements, we refer for example to [Oes04], pp. 22-23,<br />

25


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

The <strong>as</strong>set pool might be cl<strong>as</strong>sified into ”senior tr<strong>an</strong>che”, ”junior tr<strong>an</strong>che” <strong>an</strong>d ”first-<br />

loss-piece” (or ”equity tr<strong>an</strong>che”). The involved risk incre<strong>as</strong>es in that order. However,<br />

there might also be more tr<strong>an</strong>ches. The first-loss-piece is often held by the originator for<br />

several re<strong>as</strong>ons: First, it c<strong>an</strong> be interpreted <strong>as</strong> a signal for investors about the quality of<br />

the <strong>as</strong>set pool. Second, it reduces incentives accruing from agency risks due to <strong>as</strong>ymmetric<br />

information. Finally, dem<strong>an</strong>d for this tr<strong>an</strong>che is often not sufficient.<br />

Repayments are made according to the ”waterfall principle”: If c<strong>as</strong>h flows have to<br />

be distributed to investors, at first, claims of senior tr<strong>an</strong>che investors are satisfied, then<br />

junior tr<strong>an</strong>che investors receive payments, <strong>an</strong>d finally equity tr<strong>an</strong>che investors. Conversely,<br />

the most risky tr<strong>an</strong>che takes over the first losses. If there are still losses to distribute,<br />

then the junior tr<strong>an</strong>che h<strong>as</strong> to carry them, <strong>an</strong>d at l<strong>as</strong>t the senior tr<strong>an</strong>che. This is called<br />

”reverse order of seniority”. For taking over more risk, investors of the riskier tr<strong>an</strong>ches<br />

are compensated with a higher return.<br />

2.4.2 Cl<strong>as</strong>sification according to the Underlying <strong>Asset</strong><br />

After the introduction of securitisations, we present a cl<strong>as</strong>sification according to the un-<br />

derlying <strong>as</strong>set. Figure 2.8 gives <strong>an</strong> overview.<br />

Figure 2.8: Cl<strong>as</strong>sification according to the underlying <strong>as</strong>set<br />

Collateralised debt obligations (CDO) comprise collateralised lo<strong>an</strong> obligations (CLO),<br />

which are the securitised form of a lo<strong>an</strong> portfolio, <strong>an</strong>d collateralised bond obligations<br />

(CBO), which consist of a bond portfolio. Often, the borrowers of the underlying <strong>as</strong>sets<br />

are corporations.<br />

Mortgage backed securities (MBS) are <strong>as</strong>sets that are collateralised by real estate.<br />

Here, one c<strong>an</strong> differentiate between mortgages gr<strong>an</strong>ted to retail b<strong>an</strong>king customers, so-<br />

called residential mortgage backed securities (RMBS), or to corporations, so-called com-<br />

mercial mortgage backed securities (CMBS).<br />

Finally, there are <strong>as</strong>set backed securities (in a narrow sense) which c<strong>an</strong>not be cl<strong>as</strong>sified<br />

into one of the other categories. They contain for example credit card receivables, le<strong>as</strong>ing<br />

receivables <strong>an</strong>d consumer lo<strong>an</strong>s.<br />

For the scope of the thesis, we will concentrate on CDOs since they have the same<br />

underlying <strong>as</strong>sets <strong>as</strong> m<strong>an</strong>y credit derivatives, <strong>an</strong>d thus a similar risk exposure. In contr<strong>as</strong>t,<br />

[Bay06], pp. 13-17 <strong>an</strong>d [D<strong>as</strong>06], pp. 859-860.<br />

26


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

MBS for example have only little credit risk, <strong>as</strong> they are highly collateralised; in c<strong>as</strong>e of<br />

default, the recovery value is very high.<br />

2.4.3 Re<strong>as</strong>ons for the Utilisation of Securitisations<br />

In this section, we illuminate the re<strong>as</strong>ons for investors to use securitised products. We<br />

differentiate between the specific re<strong>as</strong>ons for fin<strong>an</strong>cial institutions, <strong>as</strong> they are the main<br />

market driver, <strong>an</strong>d general re<strong>as</strong>ons for investors to engage in these products.<br />

Motivation for Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Institutions to use Securitisations<br />

For b<strong>an</strong>ks, the utilisation of securitisations is appealing for several re<strong>as</strong>ons.<br />

• Risk diversification – The risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer of a securitisation c<strong>an</strong> be used to restructure<br />

the lo<strong>an</strong> portfolio of a b<strong>an</strong>k under risk-return considerations <strong>an</strong>d to deliberately re-<br />

duce risk or to enter into new risks. This is re<strong>as</strong>onable for example, if a b<strong>an</strong>k h<strong>as</strong><br />

considerable concentrations of credit risk in a certain region or vis-à-vis a certain in-<br />

dustry. Such concentrations c<strong>an</strong> be reduced by securitising a fraction of the portfolio<br />

or by investing in securitised products concentrating on other regions or industries.<br />

Hence, securitisation c<strong>an</strong> be used to m<strong>an</strong>age credit risk exposure.<br />

• Liquidity – By selling parts of their lo<strong>an</strong> portfolio, b<strong>an</strong>ks c<strong>an</strong> raise liquidity for<br />

potentially better conditions th<strong>an</strong> raising it over the capital market <strong>as</strong> debt. This<br />

might be particularly interesting for b<strong>an</strong>ks that do not have a first-cl<strong>as</strong>s credit rating.<br />

• Capital relief – Tr<strong>an</strong>sferring credit risk to third parties, c<strong>an</strong> imply both <strong>an</strong> economic<br />

<strong>an</strong>d a regulatory capital relief. Thus, flexibility is created for other risk-bearing<br />

activities.<br />

• M<strong>an</strong>agement of bal<strong>an</strong>ce sheet <strong>an</strong>d cost structure – Through securitisation, b<strong>an</strong>ks c<strong>an</strong><br />

improve their risk <strong>an</strong>d cost structure for example by generating nearly risk-free com-<br />

mission earnings while reducing total <strong>as</strong>sets. Hence, they achieve <strong>an</strong> improvement<br />

of perform<strong>an</strong>ce figures. 72<br />

Due to harmonisation <strong>an</strong>d internationalisation of markets, these motivations will prob-<br />

ably become more <strong>an</strong>d more import<strong>an</strong>t for b<strong>an</strong>ks <strong>an</strong>d so lead to <strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>ing use of<br />

securitisation.<br />

However, from a b<strong>an</strong>k’s point of view, there are some drawbacks with respect to<br />

securitisation:<br />

• Large parts of a b<strong>an</strong>k’s portfolio might be unsuitable for securitisation in c<strong>as</strong>e of non-<br />

funded types of exposure, for inst<strong>an</strong>ce revolving credits, lines of credit or derivatives.<br />

• Securitisations might be subject to restrictions. Notifications or approval by bor-<br />

rowers c<strong>an</strong> be required which might damage the client relationship.<br />

• The economic <strong>an</strong>d regulatory capital relief might be limited <strong>as</strong> b<strong>an</strong>ks often hold a<br />

large proportion of the equity tr<strong>an</strong>che. Then, only a small part of the credit risk<br />

exposure is tr<strong>an</strong>sferred.<br />

72 See [Oes04], p. 9, [D<strong>as</strong>06], pp. 851-852, [Bom05], pp. 30-31 <strong>an</strong>d [Deu97], p. 58.<br />

27


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

• Securitisations may be time-consuming <strong>an</strong>d costly regarding necessary legal steps<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the structuring of the portfolio, for example the notification <strong>an</strong>d approval of the<br />

borrower, the rating process for the tr<strong>an</strong>ches, etc.. 73<br />

After explaining the motivations for fin<strong>an</strong>cial institutions to use securitisations, we will<br />

discuss the re<strong>as</strong>ons for investors to engage in securitised products.<br />

Motivation for Investors to buy Securitised Products<br />

By securitising <strong>as</strong>set pools, <strong>an</strong>d structuring them in several tr<strong>an</strong>ches, credit risk is isolated<br />

from the original obligation <strong>an</strong>d tr<strong>an</strong>sferred to investors in different tr<strong>an</strong>ches according<br />

to individual risk-return requirements. There are several re<strong>as</strong>ons for investors to buy<br />

securitised products.<br />

• Perform<strong>an</strong>ce – Securitised products provide credit spreads that are potentially higher<br />

th<strong>an</strong> returns received from investments with a comparable risk profile <strong>an</strong>d rating. In<br />

addition, the default history is very good, which is the re<strong>as</strong>on why m<strong>an</strong>y institutional<br />

investors take part in the market.<br />

• Diversification – Securitised products constitute a way for investors to obtain a more<br />

diversified portfolio by adding a credit risk exposure to it.<br />

• Structured exposure – The products c<strong>an</strong> enable investors to achieve a credit risk<br />

exposure that is not available in the market. Furthermore, the investor h<strong>as</strong> access<br />

to structured credit risk exposure where he c<strong>an</strong> invest in different tr<strong>an</strong>ches. So, he<br />

c<strong>an</strong> determine the level of credit risk exposure he w<strong>an</strong>ts to have.<br />

• Liquidity – Often, ABS markets are more liquid th<strong>an</strong> the corporate bond market.<br />

• Possibility to participate in credit derivatives market – Some fixed income investors<br />

are – for regulatory, investment policy or administrative re<strong>as</strong>ons – not allowed or not<br />

able to invest in unfunded credit derivatives. By investing in funded 74 structures,<br />

<strong>an</strong> investor h<strong>as</strong> exposure to the sort of credit risk he is interested in. 75<br />

2.4.4 Risks related to Securitisation Markets<br />

In this section, we examine the specific risks induced by securitisations, not, however, the<br />

kind of risk tr<strong>an</strong>sferred by the securitisation. Note that these specific risks are similar to<br />

the risks related to credit derivative contracts. Table 2.3 gives <strong>an</strong> overview on the possible<br />

risks inherent in securitisations which will be described in more detail below.<br />

The risks related to securitisations c<strong>an</strong> also be cl<strong>as</strong>sified into two groups: Risks on<br />

contract level <strong>an</strong>d risks on market level. At first, we will to explain the risks on contract<br />

level.<br />

73 See [D<strong>as</strong>06], pp. 863-864 <strong>an</strong>d [Bom05], pp. 30-31, 139.<br />

74 ”Funded” me<strong>an</strong>s that the protection seller h<strong>as</strong> to make <strong>an</strong> up-front funding when entering into the<br />

contract. The protection seller, for example, buys a fraction of the securitised portfolio, <strong>an</strong>d thus takes<br />

over credit risk. (See [BIS03], p. 5.)<br />

75 See [D<strong>as</strong>06], pp. 805, 852, 864-867 [Bay06], p. 3, [Deu97], p. 58.<br />

28


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

Risks on contract level Risks on market level<br />

Counterparty risk Liquidity risk<br />

Legal risk Market risk/interest-rate risk<br />

Operational risk Agency risk<br />

Liquidity risk/prepayment risk Risk of regulatory arbitrage<br />

Table 2.3: Risks in securitisation markets<br />

• Counterparty risk – As seen in the Figure 2.7, there are numerous c<strong>as</strong>h flow streams<br />

involved in a securitisation. All of those are exposed to the inability of a counterparty<br />

to fulfil its payment obligations, which is denoted ”counterparty risk”. To reduce<br />

this kind of risk, credit enh<strong>an</strong>cements 76 c<strong>an</strong> be used.<br />

• Legal risk – There are several facets regarding legal risk <strong>as</strong>sociated with securitisa-<br />

tions.<br />

– In order to achieve the desired status of a securitisation, a fin<strong>an</strong>cial institution<br />

h<strong>as</strong> to consider m<strong>an</strong>y <strong>as</strong>pects such <strong>as</strong> regulatory, tax <strong>an</strong>d legal <strong>as</strong>pects.<br />

– Realising a securitisation, it should be ensured that in c<strong>as</strong>e of a default of <strong>an</strong><br />

involved party, the claims are enforceable.<br />

– For <strong>an</strong> effective risk m<strong>an</strong>agement, <strong>an</strong> optimal availability of information is neces-<br />

sary. Therefore, legal <strong>as</strong>pects regarding b<strong>an</strong>k secret, protection of data privacy<br />

<strong>an</strong>d disclosure requirements have to be taken into account.<br />

• Operational risk – A securitisation involves numerous parties with mutual contrac-<br />

tual obligations. This entails risks of potential losses from the failure of the technical<br />

infr<strong>as</strong>tructure, inadequate or failed internal processes or people.<br />

• Liquidity risk/prepayment risk – From the SPV’s point of view, liquidity risk emerges<br />

if there is a mismatch of the time of income streams <strong>an</strong>d the scheduled payoff streams.<br />

This also includes the prepayment risk which arises if a borrower makes use of his<br />

right to c<strong>an</strong>cel <strong>an</strong>d pays back the lo<strong>an</strong> before maturity. Then, investors have to<br />

accept foregone interest payments. 77<br />

After having addressed the risks on contract level, we will consider the risks involved<br />

in securitisations on market level. Apart from the general risks in bond markets, which<br />

have already been described in Section 2.2.2, there are more securitisation-specific risks.<br />

• Liquidity risk – On a market level, liquidity risk me<strong>an</strong>s for the SPV the inability to<br />

place the securitised bonds completely in the market. This c<strong>an</strong> lead to a liquidity<br />

squeeze for the SPV. But there is also a liquidity risk for the investor, who might be<br />

unable to trade the securitised bond in the market at <strong>an</strong>y time or without adversely<br />

affecting the price.<br />

• Market risk/interest-rate risk – Market risk describes the risk for <strong>an</strong> investor to incur<br />

a potential loss from <strong>an</strong> adverse ch<strong>an</strong>ge of the security price due to ch<strong>an</strong>ges of the<br />

market interest-rate.<br />

76 For further information on credit enh<strong>an</strong>cements, we refer to Section 2.4.1.<br />

77 See [Oes04], pp. 21-34, [Deu04], pp. 37-45.<br />

29


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

• Agency risk – A securitisation involves several parties with mutual contractual oblig-<br />

ations which – in combination with information <strong>as</strong>ymmetry – results in potential<br />

agency risk. As already explained earlier we differentiate between adverse selection<br />

<strong>an</strong>d moral hazard. 78<br />

• Regulatory arbitrage – As already explained in Section 2.3.4 regulatory arbitrage is<br />

used by fin<strong>an</strong>cial institutions to achieve a regulatory capital relief where the regula-<br />

tory capital is higher th<strong>an</strong> the economic capital due to inefficient regulatory rules.<br />

A major tool to realise this type of arbitrage is securitisation. Under the B<strong>as</strong>el I<br />

Accord, b<strong>an</strong>ks have a strong incentive to securitise lo<strong>an</strong>s towards highly rated bor-<br />

rowers, so-called ”good risks”. Then, b<strong>an</strong>ks would primarily keep the low rated<br />

lo<strong>an</strong>s, <strong>an</strong>d would thus incre<strong>as</strong>e their own probability to default resulting in a threat<br />

for the stability of the fin<strong>an</strong>cial system. Such effects are to be prevented by the<br />

implementation of the B<strong>as</strong>el II Accord, dem<strong>an</strong>ding a more risk-adjusted regulatory<br />

capital. 79<br />

On the one h<strong>an</strong>d, there are concerns from regulatory authorities that the stability of<br />

the fin<strong>an</strong>cial system might be end<strong>an</strong>gered by <strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>ing securitisation volume, <strong>as</strong> more<br />

<strong>an</strong>d more credit risk is <strong>as</strong>sumed by non-regulated investors. Moreover, from securitisations<br />

a sustainable interference of the relationship between the b<strong>an</strong>k <strong>an</strong>d the borrower might<br />

accrue.<br />

On the other h<strong>an</strong>d, there are nearly no examples of failures of ABS tr<strong>an</strong>sactions so far.<br />

ABS c<strong>an</strong> rather be considered <strong>as</strong> save investment delivering comparatively high returns.<br />

2.4.5 Tr<strong>an</strong>saction Costs<br />

As already mentioned, the tr<strong>an</strong>saction costs involved in securitised products may be very<br />

high. Costs to be covered comprise service fees, fees for the trustee, the rating agency, etc..<br />

There is a d<strong>an</strong>ger of fee maximisation by the involved parties, resulting in a considerable<br />

reduction of the available c<strong>as</strong>h flows for investors. 80<br />

2.4.6 Market<br />

The securitisation market h<strong>as</strong> grown in recent years. In the following, we provide <strong>an</strong><br />

overview on the evolution of the market <strong>an</strong>d its size. Then, we have a closer look at the<br />

market by region <strong>an</strong>d by collateral. 81<br />

Evolution <strong>an</strong>d Size<br />

Figure 2.9 shows the development of the global securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce. 82<br />

78<br />

For <strong>an</strong> expl<strong>an</strong>ation of these terms, we refer to Section 2.3.4.<br />

79<br />

See [Oes04], pp. 21-34, [Deu04], pp. 37-45, [Gre98], pp. 163-166, [Deu97], pp. 60-61.<br />

80<br />

See [Oes04], p. 27.<br />

81<br />

The information for this section is mainly taken from [Int06] <strong>an</strong>d [Eur06]. The International Fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

Services, London, also publishes datafiles on their website for all charts <strong>an</strong>d tables that are contained in<br />

its report.<br />

82<br />

The data is taken from [Int06] <strong>an</strong>d the underlying datafiles. We rearr<strong>an</strong>ged the data, also including the<br />

Emerging Markets, comprised of Latin America, Asia, E<strong>as</strong>tern Europe, Middle E<strong>as</strong>t & Africa (EEMEA).<br />

30


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

Figure 2.9: Global securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce (in USD billions)<br />

The issu<strong>an</strong>ce volume of 2005 amounts to USD 3,630 billion <strong>an</strong>d is nearly five times <strong>as</strong><br />

high <strong>as</strong> that of 1996. It c<strong>an</strong> be observed that the issu<strong>an</strong>ce volume is volatile. This c<strong>an</strong><br />

be partly attributed to the interest-rate level, <strong>as</strong> particularly MBS issu<strong>an</strong>ce is inversely<br />

correlated with interest-rate level over time; if interest-rates rise, MBS issu<strong>an</strong>ce decre<strong>as</strong>es.<br />

Other factors influencing the issu<strong>an</strong>ce activity are investors’ dem<strong>an</strong>d, development of the<br />

underlying market <strong>an</strong>d general market environment. Especially in recent years, the securi-<br />

tisation market w<strong>as</strong> driven by a broader investor b<strong>as</strong>e, including hedge funds, institutional<br />

investors, <strong>as</strong>set m<strong>an</strong>agers, retail funds <strong>an</strong>d private b<strong>an</strong>ks. These investors are looking for<br />

higher yields relative to other fixed-income markets. 83<br />

Market Breakdown<br />

The securitisation market c<strong>an</strong> be cl<strong>as</strong>sified according to different <strong>as</strong>pects. In this section,<br />

we give <strong>an</strong> overview on the market with respect to region <strong>an</strong>d collateral.<br />

By Region In Figure 2.10 we see the development <strong>an</strong>d the size of securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

in different regions over time. 84<br />

The US market clearly dominates the global securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce with a volume<br />

of USD 3,023 billion or 83% of the whole issu<strong>an</strong>ce volume in 2005, followed by Europe<br />

with 11%, Jap<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d Australia with 2% <strong>an</strong>d Emerging Markets with 1%. While all<br />

other markets almost exceptionally incre<strong>as</strong>ed since 1996, the US market experienced both<br />

incre<strong>as</strong>es <strong>an</strong>d decre<strong>as</strong>es. 85<br />

Figure 2.11 provides information regarding Europe<strong>an</strong> securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce. 86<br />

83<br />

See [Int06], pp. 1-2, 5, [Eur06], p. 1, [BIS05a], pp. 22-23.<br />

84<br />

The data is taken from [Int06] <strong>an</strong>d the underlying datafiles.<br />

85<br />

See [Int06], pp. 1-2.<br />

86<br />

The data is taken from [Int06] <strong>an</strong>d the underlying datafiles.<br />

31


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

Figure 2.10: Global securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce by region (in USD billions)<br />

UK w<strong>as</strong> the largest Europe<strong>an</strong> issuer in 2005 with a volume of USD 181 billion or 45%,<br />

followed by Spain with 13%, the Netherl<strong>an</strong>ds with 11%, Italy with 10%, <strong>an</strong>d Germ<strong>an</strong>y<br />

with 7%. Still, Germ<strong>an</strong>y incre<strong>as</strong>ed its share from 2004 to 2005 by more th<strong>an</strong> 300%, up to<br />

USD 22 billion. That way, Germ<strong>an</strong> b<strong>an</strong>ks open more funding sources <strong>an</strong>d keep pace with<br />

global trends. 87<br />

By Collateral Now, we give <strong>an</strong> overview on securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce in the US <strong>an</strong>d in<br />

Europe with respect to their collateral. 88 Figure 2.12 shows the breakdown of securitisation<br />

by collateral in the US. 89<br />

In 2005, MBS had by far the largest share of securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce (66%), followed<br />

by home equity (14%), private ABS, auto, credit card <strong>an</strong>d student lo<strong>an</strong>. The report does<br />

not explain the me<strong>an</strong>ing of ”Other” or private ABS. Furthermore, it is unclear how big<br />

87 See [Eur06], pp. 2-3, [Deu04], p. 36.<br />

88 No global breakdown by collateral w<strong>as</strong> available.<br />

89 The data is taken from [Int06] <strong>an</strong>d the underlying datafiles. We rearr<strong>an</strong>ged the data to meet our needs.<br />

32


CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

Figure 2.11: Europe<strong>an</strong> securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce by region 2005<br />

Figure 2.12: US securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce by collateral 2005<br />

the proportion of CDOs is. The only information regarding CDOs is that they incre<strong>as</strong>ed<br />

their market share of outst<strong>an</strong>ding value of ABS in the United States from 12% in 2000 to<br />

15% in 2005 <strong>an</strong>d are so the third largest sector overall. 90<br />

Figure 2.13 represents a breakdown of securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce in Europe by collateral<br />

in 2005. 91<br />

The most domin<strong>an</strong>t share of total securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce in Europe in 2005 had MBS<br />

with a proportion of 57% (thereof RMBS 45% <strong>an</strong>d CMBS 12%). In terms of size, the<br />

CDO market had the second-largest issu<strong>an</strong>ce volume with 15%. Compared to 2004, its<br />

size incre<strong>as</strong>ed by 86%. But the f<strong>as</strong>test growing product sector in 2005 w<strong>as</strong> the CMBS<br />

sector, which more th<strong>an</strong> doubled its volume in 2005 compared to 2004 holding market<br />

share of 12%. 92<br />

In this chapter, we learned a lot about credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer in general. We considered<br />

credit risk <strong>as</strong> such, traditional credit instruments <strong>an</strong>d the possibilities of credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>s-<br />

fer. Our expl<strong>an</strong>ations included a description of the functionality of credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer<br />

instruments, the ch<strong>an</strong>ces <strong>an</strong>d risks inherent in these markets <strong>an</strong>d the market evolution<br />

<strong>an</strong>d size. In the following chapter, we explain import<strong>an</strong>t credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer instruments<br />

90 See [Int06], p. 3.<br />

91 The data is taken from [Eur06].<br />

92 See [Eur06], p. 2.<br />

33


in detail.<br />

CHAPTER 2. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER<br />

Figure 2.13: Europe<strong>an</strong> securitisation issu<strong>an</strong>ce by collateral 2005<br />

34


Chapter 3<br />

<strong>Credit</strong> Risk Tr<strong>an</strong>sfer Instruments<br />

Numerous instruments c<strong>an</strong> be used for credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer. We are particularly interested<br />

in derivatives- or securitisation-b<strong>as</strong>ed instruments. In the previous chapter, we learned<br />

a lot about credit derivatives <strong>an</strong>d securitisation in general. This chapter describes m<strong>an</strong>y<br />

of the possible credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer instruments. Section 3.1 categorises derivatives- or<br />

securitisation-b<strong>as</strong>ed instruments, according to the dimensions unfunded/funded or single-<br />

name/multi-name instruments. These instruments will be described during the course<br />

of the chapter. The instruments covered, are credit default swaps (CDS)/credit default<br />

options, total return swaps, credit spread options, b<strong>as</strong>ket CDS, portfolio CDS, credit linked<br />

notes, collateralised debt obligations <strong>an</strong>d CDS indices. The covered instruments, however,<br />

are not me<strong>an</strong>t to be exhaustive, <strong>as</strong> there are m<strong>an</strong>y product variations <strong>an</strong>d continuous<br />

innovations.<br />

3.1 Derivatives- or Securitisation-b<strong>as</strong>ed Instruments<br />

Figure 3.1 gives <strong>an</strong> overview on derivatives- or securitisation-b<strong>as</strong>ed credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer<br />

instruments, which will be described in this chapter.<br />

Figure 3.1: Derivatives- or securitisation-b<strong>as</strong>ed credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer instruments<br />

One c<strong>an</strong> differentiate between the dimensions unfunded/funded or single-name/multi-<br />

name instruments. When a protection buyer enters into a funded credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer<br />

35


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

contract, he receives funds from the counterparty at inception. In contr<strong>as</strong>t, he does not<br />

receive <strong>an</strong>y funds at inception when he enters into <strong>an</strong> unfunded contract. As already ex-<br />

plained, a single-name instrument h<strong>as</strong> one reference entity, while a multi-name instrument<br />

h<strong>as</strong> a portfolio of reference entities.<br />

The overview does not contain CDS indices. The re<strong>as</strong>on is that they c<strong>an</strong>not be cl<strong>as</strong>sified<br />

into this scheme, since they are indices on synthetic reference portfolios, either being issued<br />

unfunded or funded.<br />

Besides, the overview does not contain credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer instruments that are not<br />

derivatives- or securitisation-b<strong>as</strong>ed, such <strong>as</strong> guar<strong>an</strong>tees, letters of credit, or insur<strong>an</strong>ces, <strong>as</strong><br />

they are out of scope of this thesis.<br />

3.2 <strong>Credit</strong> Default Swap/<strong>Credit</strong> Default Option<br />

Functionality<br />

A credit default swap (CDS) in its b<strong>as</strong>ic form is a bilateral contract in which the protection<br />

buyer pays a fixed periodic (typically quarterly paid) fee (CDS swap spread or premium),<br />

generally expressed in b<strong>as</strong>is points (bps) on the notional amount, over a predetermined<br />

period (maturity) to the protection seller. In exch<strong>an</strong>ge, the protection buyer receives a<br />

contingent payment from the protection seller, triggered by a credit event of a reference<br />

entity. Figure 3.2 illustrates the functionality of a CDS.<br />

Figure 3.2: <strong>Credit</strong> default swap<br />

The st<strong>an</strong>dard CDS contract is b<strong>as</strong>ed on ISDA M<strong>as</strong>ter Agreements. Moreover, it uses<br />

ISDA credit derivatives definitions <strong>an</strong>d the Short Form Confirmation for individual CDS<br />

including the following key terms <strong>an</strong>d conditions. 1<br />

• Reference entity.<br />

• Reference obligation.<br />

1 See [BIS03], p. 35, [D<strong>as</strong>06], pp. 708-709.<br />

36


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

• Maturity. 3, 5, 10 years are the most common maturities. The CDS maturity does<br />

not need to match that of a particular debt obligation.<br />

• <strong>Credit</strong> events. The st<strong>an</strong>dard CDS contract allows for the following credit events:<br />

B<strong>an</strong>kruptcy, obligation acceleration, failure to pay, restructuring of debt, <strong>an</strong>d in<br />

c<strong>as</strong>e of sovereign reference entities debt moratorium or debt repudiation. 2<br />

• Settlement method. In c<strong>as</strong>e of default, CDS c<strong>an</strong> be settled in c<strong>as</strong>h (more common in<br />

Europe) or physically (more common in the US). 3<br />

If a credit event occurs, the contract terminates, i.e. the protection buyer stops paying<br />

the periodic fee, <strong>an</strong>d the protection seller h<strong>as</strong> to compensate the protection buyer according<br />

to the stipulated settlement method.<br />

CDS c<strong>an</strong> be viewed <strong>as</strong> a kind of debt insur<strong>an</strong>ce or guar<strong>an</strong>tee. Nonetheless, there are<br />

three signific<strong>an</strong>t differences between CDS <strong>an</strong>d insur<strong>an</strong>ce-b<strong>as</strong>ed products. The notion credit<br />

event that triggers payment is broader for credit derivatives th<strong>an</strong> for a guar<strong>an</strong>tee. The<br />

protection buyer of a CDS does not need to prove that he actually h<strong>as</strong> suffered a loss in<br />

order to obtain a contingent payment. Finally, there is a st<strong>an</strong>dardised documentation for<br />

CDS, which facilitates <strong>an</strong>d promotes trading.<br />

As already seen, CDS are the most widespread instrument within the credit derivatives<br />

market, <strong>an</strong>d they are the most import<strong>an</strong>t instrument in this market. 4 This development<br />

c<strong>an</strong> be attributed to the st<strong>an</strong>dardisation of documentation, <strong>an</strong>d to low tr<strong>an</strong>saction costs<br />

due to a narrowing of bid-<strong>as</strong>k-spreads for CDS. Thus, CDS are a cost efficient alternative to<br />

insur<strong>an</strong>ce-b<strong>as</strong>ed products. Furthermore, CDS build the b<strong>as</strong>is for more complex structured<br />

products, such <strong>as</strong> synthetic CDOs, which will be explained later in this chapter.<br />

The main re<strong>as</strong>ons for using CDS are the same <strong>as</strong> for credit derivatives in general. 5 .<br />

A credit default option is very similar to a CDS contract. The central difference between<br />

them is that the protection buyer of the option does not pay a periodic fee. He rather<br />

pays <strong>an</strong> up-front fee or option premium once.<br />

Product Variations<br />

There are numerous product variations on the b<strong>as</strong>ic structure of a CDS, which is described<br />

earlier in this section. No variation is, however, <strong>as</strong> liquid <strong>an</strong>d widespread <strong>as</strong> the b<strong>as</strong>ic CDS.<br />

Here, we only w<strong>an</strong>t to show a few variations.<br />

A binary CDS (also called fixed-recovery CDS or digital CDS) differs from v<strong>an</strong>illa<br />

CDS contracts in the recovery value in c<strong>as</strong>e of default. It is stipulated in the contract in<br />

adv<strong>an</strong>ce. Hence, the uncertainty about the recovery rate is eliminated.<br />

For CDS contracts written on reference entities with a low credit quality, often two<br />

fees are quoted – <strong>an</strong> up-front fee <strong>an</strong>d a periodic fee. The former h<strong>as</strong> to be paid from the<br />

protection buyer to the protection seller at inception of the contract. The latter h<strong>as</strong> to be<br />

paid periodically, <strong>an</strong>alogous to a v<strong>an</strong>illa CDS. 6<br />

2<br />

For a description of these events we refer to [Bom05], p. 290, [D<strong>as</strong>06], pp. 713-717.<br />

3<br />

The settlement methods are described in the paragraph ”St<strong>an</strong>dardisation of Documentation” in Section<br />

2.3.6<br />

4For<br />

the size of the market we refer to 2.3.6.<br />

5<br />

For a discussion, we refer to Section 2.3.3.<br />

6<br />

For a more detailed description of product variations we refer for example to [D<strong>as</strong>06].<br />

37


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

A CDS c<strong>an</strong> also be issued in a funded version. The protection seller (investor) buys a<br />

FRN, which pays a coupon of the 3 month LIBOR plus the fixed CDS spread quarterly.<br />

If no credit event occurs, the coupon is paid until maturity. Then, the investor receives<br />

the notional amount of the FRN. However, if a credit event of the reference entity takes<br />

place, the protection seller receives the recovery value <strong>an</strong>d the contract terminates. This<br />

c<strong>an</strong> also be considered <strong>as</strong> special c<strong>as</strong>e of a credit linked note <strong>as</strong> described in Section 3.7.<br />

CDS <strong>as</strong> Market Indicators<br />

Some studies indicate, that market information is more quickly incorporated in CDS prices<br />

th<strong>an</strong> in bond prices. The main re<strong>as</strong>on is that the market for CDS is more liquid th<strong>an</strong> the<br />

bond market, particularly the corporate bond market. But there are more re<strong>as</strong>ons why<br />

CDS prices <strong>an</strong>d bond credit spreads are not absolutely high-correlated, for example tax<br />

<strong>as</strong>pects or limited possibility of short-selling in bond markets. 7<br />

Other studies come to the conclusion that CDS show a price leadership <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>ticipate<br />

credit rating ch<strong>an</strong>ges <strong>an</strong>d downgradings of the reference entity in particular. 8 In contr<strong>as</strong>t<br />

to bonds, CDS prices c<strong>an</strong>not only be viewed <strong>as</strong> indicators for a certain reference entity, but<br />

they c<strong>an</strong> also be seen <strong>as</strong> indicators of market sentiment regarding credit risk in general.<br />

Altogether, CDS prices contain subst<strong>an</strong>tial information for <strong>an</strong> early detection of potentially<br />

critical developments within the fin<strong>an</strong>cial system. 9<br />

3.3 Total Return Swap<br />

Functionality<br />

A total return swap (TRS) (or total rate of return swap) is a bilateral agreement between<br />

the total return receiver <strong>an</strong>d the total return payer. 10 The former receives all c<strong>as</strong>h flows<br />

<strong>as</strong>sociated with a reference <strong>as</strong>set without owning the <strong>as</strong>set. In return, the latter receives<br />

periodic payments which are b<strong>as</strong>ed on LIBOR plus a fixed spread with respect to the<br />

same notional amount. The payments from the total return receiver are not related to the<br />

credit-worthiness of the reference <strong>as</strong>set.<br />

The b<strong>as</strong>ic structure of a TRS, <strong>as</strong> described above, is displayed in Figure 3.3.<br />

A TRS contract c<strong>an</strong> terminate in two ways, either if the reference entity defaults, or at<br />

maturity. If no default occurs, the difference in the reference <strong>as</strong>set’s market value between<br />

maturity <strong>an</strong>d inception is calculated at maturity. If it is positive, the total return receiver<br />

obtains the difference. If it is negative, he h<strong>as</strong> to pay the difference to the total return<br />

payer.<br />

In c<strong>as</strong>e of a default of the reference entity, however, the total return receiver h<strong>as</strong> to<br />

bear the ch<strong>an</strong>ge in the value of the underlying <strong>as</strong>set by paying the difference between the<br />

market value of the reference <strong>as</strong>set at inception <strong>an</strong>d its recovery value to the total return<br />

payer. Then, the contract terminates. 11<br />

7<br />

See [Bom05], pp. 39-40, [Deu04b], pp. 1, 50-51.<br />

8<br />

The study of Zhu ([Zhu04]) confirms the price leadership of the credit derivatives market compared to<br />

the bond market. [Deu04b] shows a signific<strong>an</strong>t widening of CDS spreads before a rating downgrade.<br />

9<br />

See [Bom05], pp. 39-40, [Deu04b], pp. 1, 50-51, [Zhu04], p. 15.<br />

10<br />

The terms are taken from swap markets.<br />

11<br />

See [Bom05], p. 85, [BOW03], pp. 212-213, [BR04], p. 21.<br />

38


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

Figure 3.3: Total return swap<br />

From a receiver’s perspective, a TRS is a me<strong>an</strong>s to replicate the total perform<strong>an</strong>ce of a<br />

reference <strong>as</strong>set. Thus, it is used to synthetically create the c<strong>as</strong>h flows of a reference <strong>as</strong>set,<br />

which for example c<strong>an</strong>not be bought by the investor, such <strong>as</strong> a lo<strong>an</strong>, or does not exist, for<br />

inst<strong>an</strong>ce with respect to maturity. Consequently, TRS c<strong>an</strong> be used to synthesise <strong>as</strong>sets in<br />

order to meet the investor’s individual needs.<br />

From a payer’s perspective, a TRS tr<strong>an</strong>sfers the full risk of a reference <strong>as</strong>set to the<br />

receiver, including default risk <strong>an</strong>d credit spread risk accruing from a ch<strong>an</strong>ge in credit<br />

quality of the reference entity. Thus, TRS c<strong>an</strong> be considered <strong>as</strong> hedging vehicle, while<br />

maintaining the client relationship.<br />

Motivations for investors to enter into TRS contracts are the same <strong>as</strong> for credit deriv-<br />

atives in general, <strong>as</strong> discussed in Section 2.3.3. One of the main re<strong>as</strong>ons, however, is the<br />

ability to leverage credit risk exposure, since no initial investment is necessary at inception.<br />

The counterparty risk accruing from TRS contracts c<strong>an</strong> be reduced by collateralisation<br />

or netting agreements. Furthermore, TRS are particularly interesting for investors which<br />

incur high funding costs, because they c<strong>an</strong> act <strong>as</strong> total return receivers. That way, they<br />

c<strong>an</strong> synthetically own the reference <strong>as</strong>set while avoiding the funding disadv<strong>an</strong>tage, <strong>as</strong> the<br />

payments to the total return payer are lower th<strong>an</strong> fin<strong>an</strong>cing a purch<strong>as</strong>e of the reference<br />

<strong>as</strong>set. But highly rated total return payers c<strong>an</strong> benefit from a TRS contract too, <strong>as</strong> they<br />

c<strong>an</strong> thereby earn a certain spread over their funding costs.<br />

A TRS contract is usually b<strong>as</strong>ed on ISDA M<strong>as</strong>ter Agreement, but, in contr<strong>as</strong>t to CDS,<br />

there is no st<strong>an</strong>dard confirmation for these contracts. 12<br />

Product Variations<br />

In this paragraph, we give <strong>an</strong> idea of different variations on the b<strong>as</strong>ic structure of TRS. It<br />

is, however, not me<strong>an</strong>t to be exhaustive.<br />

A st<strong>an</strong>dard TRS terminates at default of the reference entity. Though, there is a<br />

variation in which the contract would continue until maturity.<br />

12 See [BIS03], p. 35, [Bom05], p. 85.<br />

39


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

In <strong>an</strong>other variation, the TRS does not only refer to one reference <strong>as</strong>set, but to a<br />

portfolio or bond index <strong>as</strong> reference <strong>as</strong>set.<br />

Furthermore, the total return payer might not receive floating payments b<strong>as</strong>ed on<br />

LIBOR but fixed interest payments on the notional amount. 13<br />

3.4 <strong>Credit</strong> Spread Option<br />

Functionality<br />

A credit spread option is <strong>an</strong> option on the spread of a defaultable reference <strong>as</strong>set (e.g.<br />

a bond) over a reference yield (e.g. LIBOR). We c<strong>an</strong> differentiate between credit spread<br />

call or credit spread put options. The call (put) option gives the buyer – in return for a<br />

premium payment to the option seller – the right but not the obligation to buy (sell) the<br />

reference <strong>as</strong>set at maturity (Europe<strong>an</strong>) or until maturity (Americ<strong>an</strong>) at the price implied<br />

by the strike spread <strong>an</strong>d the reference yield.<br />

Thus, a buyer of a call option benefits from <strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>e in credit quality. Then, he c<strong>an</strong><br />

buy the reference <strong>as</strong>set for a price implied by the strike spread plus the reference yield,<br />

which is lower th<strong>an</strong> the market value of the reference <strong>as</strong>set. In contr<strong>as</strong>t, a buyer of a put<br />

option benefits from a decre<strong>as</strong>e in credit quality, <strong>as</strong> he c<strong>an</strong> sell for a higher price th<strong>an</strong> the<br />

market value. If a default occurs, a put option is normally exercised immediately.<br />

There is no st<strong>an</strong>dard confirmation for credit spread products according to ISDA. 14<br />

Product Variations<br />

Premiums for a credit spread product c<strong>an</strong> be paid up-front or in swap form.<br />

A credit spread put option may be knocked-out on default of the reference entity, which<br />

me<strong>an</strong>s that the option is worthless immediately. 15<br />

The strike spread c<strong>an</strong> be represented by a fixed spread over a reference yield or by a<br />

fixed spread between two credit sensitive <strong>as</strong>sets. 16<br />

A credit spread option c<strong>an</strong>not only be settled physically, but also in c<strong>as</strong>h. If the option<br />

is exercised, the seller h<strong>as</strong> to pay the difference between the price of the reference <strong>as</strong>set<br />

implied by the strike spread plus the reference yield, <strong>an</strong>d the market price to the buyer. 17<br />

3.5 B<strong>as</strong>ket <strong>Credit</strong> Default Swap<br />

Functionality<br />

A b<strong>as</strong>ket credit default swap is a credit derivative, comparable to a single-name CDS,<br />

that is linked to a b<strong>as</strong>ket or portfolio of <strong>as</strong>sets of more th<strong>an</strong> one reference entity. It is a<br />

bilateral contract in which the protection buyer pays a fixed periodic fee (swap spread) over<br />

a predetermined period to the protection seller. In return, the protection buyer receives<br />

a contingent payment in c<strong>as</strong>e of the k th default of <strong>an</strong>y reference entity in a b<strong>as</strong>ket of n,<br />

13 For a more detailed description of product variations, we refer for example to [Bom05], pp. 89-90.<br />

14 See [D<strong>as</strong>06], p. 691.<br />

15 See [Cha05], p. 158.<br />

16 See [D<strong>as</strong>06], p. 683.<br />

17 See [BR04], p. 25, [Cha05], p. 158.<br />

40


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

n ≥ k, during the life of the contract. Such a product is also denoted <strong>as</strong> k th -to-default<br />

swap or k th -to-default b<strong>as</strong>ket. The most common form of b<strong>as</strong>ket CDS are first-to-default<br />

(FtD) swaps. B<strong>as</strong>ket CDS typically include five to ten reference entities.<br />

A b<strong>as</strong>ket credit default swap c<strong>an</strong> terminate in two ways, either if the k th default in the<br />

b<strong>as</strong>ket occurs during the life, or at maturity. In c<strong>as</strong>e of a default of the k th reference <strong>as</strong>set,<br />

the protection seller h<strong>as</strong> to pay the difference between the notional amount of the reference<br />

<strong>as</strong>set <strong>an</strong>d the recovery value. Such a payment, however, does not affect the validity of<br />

other potential b<strong>as</strong>ket CDS that reference to the same portfolio.<br />

The parties to the contract c<strong>an</strong>not only agree on c<strong>as</strong>h settlement in c<strong>as</strong>e of default,<br />

but also on physical settlement, which is described in the paragraph ”St<strong>an</strong>dardisation of<br />

Documentation” in Section 2.3.6.<br />

Besides the general re<strong>as</strong>ons for investors to enter into credit derivatives contracts, <strong>as</strong><br />

described in Section 2.3.3, there are also specific re<strong>as</strong>ons for using b<strong>as</strong>ket CDS.<br />

For the protection buyer, a b<strong>as</strong>ket CDS is a possibility to buy protection for a b<strong>as</strong>ket<br />

of credit risks in a single tr<strong>an</strong>saction. Moreover, b<strong>as</strong>ket CDS are normally less expensive<br />

th<strong>an</strong> purch<strong>as</strong>ing protection for each reference entity through single-name CDS. The re<strong>as</strong>on<br />

is that a k th -to-default swap only protects the protection buyer from the k th default.<br />

Consequently, he would have to bear default related losses accruing from defaults other<br />

th<strong>an</strong> the k th default if he did not buy further protection.<br />

For the protection seller, a b<strong>as</strong>ket CDS is a possibility to get exposed to a b<strong>as</strong>ket of<br />

credit risks in a single tr<strong>an</strong>saction.<br />

First-to-Default Swap As already mentioned, the FtD-swaps are the most import<strong>an</strong>t<br />

form of b<strong>as</strong>ket CDS. Therefore, we describe the characteristics <strong>an</strong>d challenges related to<br />

these instruments in more detail.<br />

B<strong>as</strong>ket CDS c<strong>an</strong> be viewed <strong>as</strong> a me<strong>an</strong>s of yield enh<strong>an</strong>cement, while limiting the down-<br />

side risk. The premium for a FtD-swap is generally higher th<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>y single-name CDS<br />

premium of the individual reference entities in the b<strong>as</strong>ket since the b<strong>as</strong>ket c<strong>an</strong> have a<br />

lower credit quality th<strong>an</strong> the ”average” credit quality of the reference entities contained in<br />

the b<strong>as</strong>ket. This fact c<strong>an</strong> be explained by two re<strong>as</strong>ons, default correlation <strong>an</strong>d leverage.<br />

• Default correlation: If the probabilities of default of the b<strong>as</strong>ket reference entities<br />

are independent, the fair premium for a FtD-swap is supposed to be approximately<br />

the sum of the premiums over all reference entities. If, however, the probabilities<br />

of default are highly correlated, the premium of a FtD-swap is approximately the<br />

premium of the reference entity with the highest probability of default. 18<br />

• Leverage: As he is exposed to a b<strong>as</strong>ket of credit risks, the protection seller of a<br />

FtD-swap h<strong>as</strong> a leveraged exposure but, his maximum loss is limited to the highest<br />

notional amount of the portfolio’s reference <strong>as</strong>set. 19<br />

18 See [D<strong>as</strong>06], p. 778, [Bom05], p. 101, [BOW03], p. 218.<br />

19 See [D<strong>as</strong>06], p. 778, [Bom05], p. 101.<br />

41


Product Variations<br />

CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

Variations on b<strong>as</strong>ket CDS include, for example, loss limits. Then, the loss for the protec-<br />

tion seller is limited, for inst<strong>an</strong>ce to 50% of the notional amount, in c<strong>as</strong>e of default. This<br />

structure is similar to a binary CDS 20 .<br />

A Note on the Pricing of Multi-Name <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives<br />

The pricing of b<strong>as</strong>ket CDS, but also the pricing of multi-name credit derivatives in general,<br />

is challenging in practice, <strong>as</strong> there are a number of determin<strong>an</strong>ts for the premiums. We<br />

describe the most import<strong>an</strong>t determin<strong>an</strong>ts in the following.<br />

• Number of reference entities in the b<strong>as</strong>ket: The more reference entities contained in<br />

the b<strong>as</strong>ket, the higher the probability of default of <strong>an</strong>y reference entity <strong>an</strong>d hence,<br />

the higher the premium will be.<br />

• <strong>Credit</strong> quality <strong>an</strong>d expected recovery rate of each reference entity: The worse the<br />

credit-worthiness of a reference entity <strong>an</strong>d the lower the expected recovery rates, the<br />

higher the premium will be.<br />

• Default correlation 21 between reference entities. As already explained above for<br />

FtD-swaps, default correlation h<strong>as</strong> a subst<strong>an</strong>tial influence on the premium. The<br />

higher the default correlation between the reference entities, the lower the premium<br />

for a FtD-swap, but the higher the premium for a k th -to-default swap, k ≥ 2.<br />

This seems counterintuitive at first. A closer look at the nature of these contracts<br />

proves otherwise. With low default correlation between the reference entities, the<br />

protection seller of a FtD-swap is exposed to nearly uncorrelated sources of risks. On<br />

the contrary, with a high default correlation, the protection seller of a FtD-swap is<br />

mainly exposed to one source of risk, therefore the premium is lower. When default<br />

correlation becomes very high, the premium will be similar to the premium for a<br />

single-name CDS on the reference entity with the highest probability to default.<br />

Considering a k th -to-default swap with k ≥ 2, a higher default correlation incre<strong>as</strong>es<br />

the probability that defaults occur together. Hence, the protection sellers of the k th -<br />

loss face a higher risk of having to cover a loss <strong>an</strong>d therefore need to be compensated<br />

with a higher premium. 22<br />

3.6 Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> Default Swap<br />

Functionality<br />

A portfolio credit default swap is similar to a b<strong>as</strong>ket CDS. It is also a credit derivative that<br />

is linked to a portfolio of <strong>as</strong>sets of more th<strong>an</strong> one reference entity. The main difference,<br />

however, is that the portfolio is subdivided into loss-pieces (the first-loss piece, the second-<br />

loss piece, etc.), which are prespecified in size. The first-loss piece, for inst<strong>an</strong>ce, carries a<br />

20 A binary CDS is described in the paragraph ”Product Variations” in Section 3.2<br />

21 A very popular way to model correlated default times for a portfolio of credit risks is the one-factor<br />

copula approach <strong>as</strong> described in Section 5.4.2.<br />

22 See [Bom05], pp. 101-105, 255-256.<br />

42


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

certain percentage, for example 10%, of default-related losses of the portfolio. Hence, the<br />

protection seller is exposed to a prespecified size of default-related losses, but not to the<br />

number of defaults. For obtaining this protection, the protection buyer of a portfolio CDS<br />

makes periodic payments to the protection seller.<br />

In c<strong>as</strong>e of default, the investor, who is accountable for the respective loss-piece, h<strong>as</strong> to<br />

pay the difference between the par values <strong>an</strong>d the recovery values to the protection buyer<br />

<strong>as</strong> long <strong>as</strong> all payments do not exceed the original size of his loss piece. Otherwise, the<br />

protection seller of the next loss piece h<strong>as</strong> to cover default-related losses. After a payment<br />

from the protection seller to the protection buyer, the loss piece is reduced accordingly, <strong>an</strong>d<br />

usually also the premium payment which is made by the protection buyer. If a protection<br />

seller h<strong>as</strong> covered the maximum amount of losses, the contract terminates immediately.<br />

Otherwise, it terminates at maturity.<br />

The contract parties c<strong>an</strong>not only agree on c<strong>as</strong>h settlement, but they c<strong>an</strong> also agree on<br />

physical settlement. 23<br />

Besides the general re<strong>as</strong>ons for investors to enter into portfolio CDS, <strong>as</strong> described in<br />

Section 2.3.3, there are also specific re<strong>as</strong>ons which are very similar to the re<strong>as</strong>ons for using<br />

b<strong>as</strong>ket CDS.<br />

For both, the protection buyer <strong>an</strong>d the protection seller, portfolio CDS allow to tr<strong>an</strong>sfer<br />

the credit risk related to a portfolio or to get exposed to it in one single tr<strong>an</strong>saction. This<br />

is a more cost efficient way th<strong>an</strong> realising a similar protection structure by several single-<br />

name CDS.<br />

From the protection buyer’s perspective, portfolio CDS are a possibility to obtain<br />

partial or complete protection against default-related losses, according to his needs.<br />

For a protection seller, portfolio CDS are a possibility to achieve a leveraged credit<br />

risk exposure with limited downside risk, since he is exposed to a complete portfolio while<br />

the maximum loss is limited. Furthermore, portfolio CDS allow with one tr<strong>an</strong>saction<br />

to have a credit risk exposure to a diversified portfolio. Protection sellers who w<strong>an</strong>t to<br />

carry less risk, c<strong>an</strong> enter into a higher-order-loss product, for example a second-loss piece.<br />

Hence, a portfolio CDS gives the investor the possibility to invest according to his own<br />

risk propensity.<br />

Here, we remark that the structure of portfolio CDS build the foundation for synthetic<br />

collateralised debt obligations (CDO), which experienced <strong>an</strong> enormous growth in recent<br />

years. 24<br />

Product Variations<br />

Portfolio CDS are less st<strong>an</strong>dardised th<strong>an</strong>, for example, single-name CDS. Therefore, they<br />

appear in numerous variations.<br />

Settlement in c<strong>as</strong>e of default c<strong>an</strong> be agreed <strong>as</strong> immediate or deferred settlement. The<br />

premium payment made by the protection seller may not be reduced after a default-related<br />

payment.<br />

It is not necessary that the reference portfolio consists of bonds or lo<strong>an</strong>s. It c<strong>an</strong> rather<br />

contain only single-name CDS. This could be attractive for market particip<strong>an</strong>ts who sold<br />

23 This is described in paragraph ”St<strong>an</strong>dardisation of Documentation” in Section 2.3.6<br />

24 CDOs in general, <strong>an</strong>d synthetic CDOs in particular are described in Section 3.8.<br />

43


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

protection with CDS but then w<strong>an</strong>t to tr<strong>an</strong>sfer a part or the complete credit risk accruing<br />

from the CDS contracts via portfolio CDS.<br />

3.7 <strong>Credit</strong> Linked Note<br />

Functionality<br />

A credit linked note (CLN) is a coupon paying security with <strong>an</strong> embedded credit derivative.<br />

Thus, it is a funded way to mimic c<strong>as</strong>h flows of a credit derivative contract. The CLN<br />

investor buys a CLN from the CLN issuer, that c<strong>an</strong> be a b<strong>an</strong>k, a SPV 25 or a corporation.<br />

The issuer in turn enters into a credit derivatives contract (often a CDS contract) with a<br />

protection buyer referring to the same reference entity, amounting to the notional amount<br />

of the CLN <strong>an</strong>d having the same maturity <strong>as</strong> the CLN. He invests the notional amount<br />

in a high-grade collateral, for example a government bond, with the same or a similar<br />

maturity <strong>as</strong> the CLN. The CLN investor receives coupon payments compensating him for<br />

the premium payment from the credit derivative contract, the interest-rate payment from<br />

the high-grade collateral, net of administration fees for the issuer. The coupon rate c<strong>an</strong><br />

be fixed or floating. In the latter c<strong>as</strong>e it is expressed, for example, <strong>as</strong> LIBOR plus a fixed<br />

spread.<br />

The b<strong>as</strong>ic structure of a CLN, <strong>as</strong> described above, is displayed in Figure 3.4. 26<br />

Figure 3.4: <strong>Credit</strong> linked note<br />

A CLN either terminates at maturity or if a credit event of the reference entity takes<br />

place. If no default occurs, both the credit derivative contract <strong>an</strong>d the CLN terminate at<br />

25 More information regarding SPVs c<strong>an</strong> be found in Section 2.4.1.<br />

26 This figure is following a similar figure in [Bom05], p. 124.<br />

44


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

maturity <strong>an</strong>d the investor receives the l<strong>as</strong>t coupon payment <strong>an</strong>d the notional amount of<br />

the CLN.<br />

Though, if a default occurs, the investor h<strong>as</strong> to carry the default related loss. After the<br />

issuer paid the difference between the notional amount of the derivative contract <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

recovery value from the high-grade collateral to the protection buyer, the investor receives<br />

the remaining sum from the high-grade investment, which is approximately the recovery<br />

value. Then, both the CLN <strong>an</strong>d the credit derivative contract terminate.<br />

From <strong>an</strong> investor’s point of view, a CLN investment c<strong>an</strong> be compared to direct in-<br />

vestment in a debt instrument issued by the reference entity, where the investor also h<strong>as</strong><br />

to carry the whole loss <strong>an</strong>d the debt instrument does not exist <strong>an</strong>y longer in c<strong>as</strong>e of de-<br />

fault. Otherwise, he receives the stipulated coupon payments <strong>an</strong>d the notional amount at<br />

maturity. But CLNs bear more risks th<strong>an</strong> a direct debt investment, for inst<strong>an</strong>ce there is<br />

counterparty risk towards <strong>an</strong> additionally involved party, the SPV.<br />

CLNs, however, c<strong>an</strong> also be rated by a rating agency. The major agencies mainly use<br />

<strong>an</strong> approach considering both the credit risk of the issuer <strong>an</strong>d of the reference entity. Thus,<br />

the rating also takes into account the counterparty risk involved in a CLN. 27<br />

For investors, CLNs offer several adv<strong>an</strong>tages:<br />

• They enable investors, who only w<strong>an</strong>t to enter into funded investments <strong>as</strong> they are<br />

familiar with that kind of investing, to engage in credit derivatives.<br />

• CLNs enable investors, who are – for regulatory restrictions or due to internal in-<br />

vestment policies – not allowed to enter into credit derivative contracts, to invest in<br />

them <strong>an</strong>yway.<br />

• A CLN allows investors to enter into credit derivative contracts while avoiding ad-<br />

ministrative issues of derivative tr<strong>an</strong>sactions, <strong>as</strong> there are for example high system<br />

requirements <strong>an</strong>d the need for <strong>an</strong> ISDA M<strong>as</strong>ter Agreement. Hence, documentation<br />

obligations <strong>an</strong>d setup costs c<strong>an</strong> be reduced.<br />

• By employing CLNs, tradable products c<strong>an</strong> be created which are otherwise not<br />

available to certain investors, such <strong>as</strong> corporate lo<strong>an</strong>s. 28<br />

By me<strong>an</strong>s of CLNs, the r<strong>an</strong>ge of market particip<strong>an</strong>ts in the credit derivatives market<br />

h<strong>as</strong> been exp<strong>an</strong>ded. Now, it is also possible, for example for institutional investors <strong>an</strong>d<br />

mutual funds, to enter into such contracts.<br />

From issuers’ perspective, a CLN is <strong>an</strong> additional me<strong>an</strong>s of hedging their exposure in<br />

credit derivatives positions.<br />

Product Variations<br />

There are m<strong>an</strong>y product variations of CLN. The type explained above is the most common<br />

type, using a CDS <strong>as</strong> a credit derivative contract. Even on that structure, there are m<strong>an</strong>y<br />

variations, which include a callable structure (the issuer is allowed to call the note prior to<br />

maturity) or a guar<strong>an</strong>teed principal structure (the investor receives a guar<strong>an</strong>teed principal<br />

27 See [D<strong>as</strong>06], pp. 808-809.<br />

28 See [Bom05], pp. 123-125, [D<strong>as</strong>06], pp. 805-806<br />

45


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

payment in c<strong>as</strong>e of default). As already mentioned, other credit derivatives c<strong>an</strong> also be used<br />

to build up a CLN. There are total return swap linked notes, credit spread linked notes,<br />

first to default notes <strong>an</strong>d CLN using a portfolio CDS <strong>as</strong> embedded credit derivative. 29<br />

CLN with a credit derivative that h<strong>as</strong> a portfolio <strong>as</strong> underlying <strong>as</strong>set allows the investor<br />

to be exposed to a pool of (diversified) reference entities in a single tr<strong>an</strong>saction.<br />

3.8 Collateralised Debt Obligation<br />

Collateralised Debt Obligations (CDOs) are instruments which redistribute the credit risk<br />

of a portfolio into tr<strong>an</strong>ches with different risk <strong>an</strong>d return characteristics. There are two<br />

main types of CDOs – the traditional CDO, with a portfolio securitisation <strong>an</strong>d the synthetic<br />

CDO, that uses credit derivatives to mimic the c<strong>as</strong>h flows of a traditional CDO. Both are<br />

described in detail below.<br />

3.8.1 Traditional CDO (True Sales Securitisation)<br />

Functionality<br />

Traditional CDOs usually have a lo<strong>an</strong> or a bond portfolio <strong>as</strong> underlying <strong>as</strong>set. Corre-<br />

spondingly, they are denoted collateralised lo<strong>an</strong> obligation (CLO) or collateralised bond<br />

obligation (CBO). Though, the functionality is the same. Therefore, we only describe it<br />

exemplary for a CLO. The b<strong>as</strong>ic structure of a traditional CLO <strong>an</strong>d the main involved<br />

parties are shown in Figure 3.5. The functionality is very similar to that of a securitisation<br />

<strong>as</strong> explained in Section 2.4.1.<br />

Figure 3.5: Collateralised lo<strong>an</strong> obligation<br />

29 For a detailed description of the functionality of these products <strong>an</strong>d their variations, we refer to [D<strong>as</strong>06],<br />

pp. 811-827.<br />

46


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

The initiative for a CLO tr<strong>an</strong>saction is taken by the originator, which is usually a<br />

b<strong>an</strong>k selling a lo<strong>an</strong> portfolio to a SPV 30 . In order to fin<strong>an</strong>ce the purch<strong>as</strong>e of the lo<strong>an</strong><br />

portfolio, the SPV issues securities which constitute a claim for the investors to interest <strong>an</strong>d<br />

instalment payments (net of administration fees) from the lo<strong>an</strong>s. The SPV in turn issues<br />

securities in different tr<strong>an</strong>ches that reflect a different level of risk <strong>an</strong>d seniority. Figure 3.5<br />

shows three tr<strong>an</strong>ches. A CLO, however, c<strong>an</strong> have more or less tr<strong>an</strong>ches. At the coupon<br />

payment dates, the c<strong>as</strong>h flows are distributed according to the waterfall principle 31 , i.e.<br />

the investors receive payments in <strong>an</strong> order according to seniority of their tr<strong>an</strong>che beginning<br />

with the most senior tr<strong>an</strong>che. Consequently, the losses are distributed in the reverse order.<br />

Accordingly, the investors receive a higher coupon for less senior tr<strong>an</strong>ches to compensate<br />

the higher risk.<br />

The CDO tr<strong>an</strong>ches are rated by a rating agency. This procedure is necessary to find<br />

investors. Ratings inform about the credit-worthiness <strong>an</strong>d risk of the different tr<strong>an</strong>ches.<br />

This is import<strong>an</strong>t due to the lack of the investor’s information regarding the underlying<br />

<strong>as</strong>set pool. There are several criteria taken into account by rating agencies. They comprise<br />

the <strong>as</strong>set quality, a c<strong>as</strong>h flow <strong>an</strong>alysis, involved market <strong>an</strong>d legal risk <strong>an</strong>d the skills of the<br />

<strong>as</strong>set m<strong>an</strong>ager. 32<br />

By rating the tr<strong>an</strong>ches, the liquidity of the securities c<strong>an</strong> be incre<strong>as</strong>ed. This is why<br />

rating agencies are often involved in the structuring process of the securities to determine<br />

the required credit enh<strong>an</strong>cements 33 in order to reach the target rating. Typically, the<br />

equity tr<strong>an</strong>che is not rated. It is often taken over (at le<strong>as</strong>t in parts) by the originator <strong>as</strong><br />

a further signal for the credit-worthiness of the <strong>as</strong>set pool.<br />

The trustee represents investors’ interests <strong>an</strong>d supervises the <strong>as</strong>set pool m<strong>an</strong>agement<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the correctness of c<strong>as</strong>h inflows <strong>an</strong>d outflows.<br />

The main driver for b<strong>an</strong>ks <strong>an</strong>d for investors to use CDOs are the same <strong>as</strong> already<br />

explained in Section 2.4.3. For b<strong>an</strong>ks, they comprise risk diversification, liquidity, capital<br />

relief, m<strong>an</strong>agement of the bal<strong>an</strong>ce sheet <strong>an</strong>d cost structure.<br />

From <strong>an</strong> investor’s point of view, securitisations entail possible higher returns, diversi-<br />

fication, a structured credit exposure <strong>an</strong>d possibly more liquidity th<strong>an</strong> the corporate bond<br />

market. 34 In addition, particularly CLOs allow investors to participate in markets where<br />

they were traditionally excluded.<br />

Product Variations<br />

Product variations, also taking into account different drivers for CDO tr<strong>an</strong>sactions, are<br />

described in Section 3.8.3 for both true sales <strong>an</strong>d synthetic securitisation.<br />

30<br />

More information regarding SPVs c<strong>an</strong> be found in Section 2.4.1.<br />

31<br />

The waterfall principle is explained in more detail in Section 2.4.1.<br />

32<br />

For more information regarding the rating criteria for CDO tr<strong>an</strong>ches, we refer to [Sta02] <strong>an</strong>d to [D<strong>as</strong>06],<br />

pp. 858-862.<br />

33<br />

Typical forms of credit enh<strong>an</strong>cements include for example subordination, overcollateralisation, c<strong>as</strong>h<br />

reserves <strong>an</strong>d fin<strong>an</strong>cial guar<strong>an</strong>tees. For more details we refer to Section 2.4.1.<br />

34<br />

For a detailed expl<strong>an</strong>ation we refer to Section 2.4.3.<br />

47


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

3.8.2 Synthetic CDO (Synthetic Securitisation)<br />

Functionality<br />

Having seen the b<strong>as</strong>ic structure of traditional CDOs, it is not difficult to underst<strong>an</strong>d<br />

the structure of synthetic CDOs. Figure 3.6 shows the b<strong>as</strong>ic structure of a synthetic<br />

securitisation exemplary for a synthetic CLO.<br />

Figure 3.6: Collateralised synthetic lo<strong>an</strong> obligation<br />

Unlike a traditional CLO, the originator does not sell the lo<strong>an</strong> portfolio to the SPV.<br />

The originator rather enters <strong>as</strong> protection buyer into a credit derivative contract (usually<br />

a series of single-name CDS or a portfolio CDS) with the SPV. Hence, only the credit<br />

risk <strong>as</strong>sociated with the portfolio is tr<strong>an</strong>sferred while keeping the lo<strong>an</strong>s in the bal<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

sheet. The SPV issues CLNs in different tr<strong>an</strong>ches. The SPV invests the proceeds of the<br />

CLNs in a high-grade collateral, for example AAA-rated <strong>as</strong>sets, with the same or a similar<br />

maturity <strong>as</strong> the CLN. The CLN investors receive coupon payments compensating them for<br />

the premium payment from the credit derivative contract <strong>an</strong>d the interest-rate payment<br />

from the high-grade collateral, net of administration fees for the issuer.<br />

If there are no defaults in the underlying portfolio, the CLN investors receive their<br />

regular coupon payments. At maturity, the credit derivative contract terminates <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

investors receive the l<strong>as</strong>t coupon payment <strong>an</strong>d the notional amount.<br />

If, however, a default occurs, the CDO investors have to absorb all default related<br />

losses, starting with the most junior tr<strong>an</strong>che investors. Then, the SPV liquidates a part<br />

of the high-grade investment to cover the loss in the underlying portfolio <strong>an</strong>d the no-<br />

tional amount of the corresponding CLN tr<strong>an</strong>che is reduced accordingly while the spread<br />

(expressed in bps of the notional amount) remains the same.<br />

At the coupon payment dates, the c<strong>as</strong>h flows are distributed according to the waterfall<br />

48


principle. 35<br />

CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

Synthetic CDO tr<strong>an</strong>ches c<strong>an</strong> also be rated. Typically, they are rated by a major rating<br />

agency to incre<strong>as</strong>e the liquidity of the tr<strong>an</strong>ches. 36<br />

From <strong>an</strong> originator’s perspective a synthetic securitisation is the same <strong>as</strong> to enter into<br />

a credit derivative contract. Therefore, the main drivers for the lo<strong>an</strong> originator to use<br />

a synthetic securitisation are the same <strong>as</strong> the specific re<strong>as</strong>ons for fin<strong>an</strong>cial institutions<br />

to enter into a credit derivative contract <strong>as</strong> explained in Section 2.3.3. They comprise<br />

economic <strong>an</strong>d regulatory capital m<strong>an</strong>agement while maintaining the client relationship.<br />

Furthermore, it may save costs compared to a traditional CDO because of high legal costs<br />

involved in a true sales securitisation <strong>an</strong>d high costs for borrower approval <strong>an</strong>d borrower<br />

notification process.<br />

For <strong>an</strong> investor, investing in synthetic CDOs is rather similar to investing in traditional<br />

CDOs. Therefore, the motivations are similar to buy securitised products <strong>as</strong> already<br />

described in Section 2.4.3 for securitisation in general <strong>an</strong>d in Section 3.8.1 for traditional<br />

CDOs in particular. Contrary to a traditional CDO, synthetic CDOs do not involve<br />

prepayment risk.<br />

Product Variations<br />

Besides fully funded synthetic securitisations, there are also partially funded structures,<br />

where the SPV acts <strong>as</strong> protection buyer of a super senior swap. The investor in that swap<br />

acts <strong>as</strong> protection seller <strong>an</strong>d receives premium payments in return. The remaining credit<br />

risk in the underlying portfolio is securitised in different tr<strong>an</strong>ches via CLNs <strong>an</strong>d sold to<br />

investors <strong>as</strong> described above.<br />

Furthermore, there are product variations taking into account different drivers for<br />

CDO tr<strong>an</strong>sactions. They are described in Section 3.8.3 for both true sales <strong>an</strong>d synthetic<br />

securitisation.<br />

3.8.3 Cl<strong>as</strong>sification of CDO Tr<strong>an</strong>sactions<br />

There are several cl<strong>as</strong>sification schemes for CDO tr<strong>an</strong>sactions. One cl<strong>as</strong>sification w<strong>as</strong><br />

already introduced, namely the differentiation between a funded or a synthetic structure<br />

with respect to the underlying portfolio <strong>as</strong> explained in the Sections 3.8.1 <strong>an</strong>d 3.8.2. In<br />

the following, we will briefly describe more cl<strong>as</strong>sifications.<br />

Bal<strong>an</strong>ce Sheet versus Arbitrage Structure<br />

Bal<strong>an</strong>ce sheet structures are driven by the originator who w<strong>an</strong>ts to tr<strong>an</strong>sfer credit risk<br />

for various re<strong>as</strong>ons. The re<strong>as</strong>ons may comprise capital relief, credit risk m<strong>an</strong>agement or<br />

funding <strong>an</strong>d reduction of bal<strong>an</strong>ce sheet size (only in c<strong>as</strong>e of a true sales securitisation).<br />

This kind of structure is mainly used for CLOs.<br />

Arbitrage structures are generally initiated by investment b<strong>an</strong>ks or <strong>as</strong>set m<strong>an</strong>agers who<br />

w<strong>an</strong>t to profit from price differences between the market price of the <strong>as</strong>set pool <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

35 For <strong>an</strong> expl<strong>an</strong>ation of the waterfall principle, see for example 3.8.1.<br />

36 For more information regarding the rating process, we refer to Section 3.8.1.<br />

49


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

price for securitised risk in a structured form. Furthermore, the CLN issuer benefits from<br />

m<strong>an</strong>agement <strong>an</strong>d administration fees.<br />

C<strong>as</strong>h Flow versus Market Value Structure<br />

C<strong>as</strong>h flow structures are CDO tr<strong>an</strong>sactions where payments to the CDO investors are<br />

secured <strong>an</strong>d made by the c<strong>as</strong>h flows generated by the underlying <strong>as</strong>set pool. This structure<br />

is usually used in static tr<strong>an</strong>sactions with a predetermined <strong>as</strong>set pool of either lo<strong>an</strong>s or<br />

bonds. 37<br />

Market value structures are similar to c<strong>as</strong>h flow structures. However, they are used for<br />

m<strong>an</strong>aged (or dynamic) CDO structures, where the portfolio credit risk is actively m<strong>an</strong>aged<br />

by a portfolio m<strong>an</strong>ager who h<strong>as</strong> to optimise the return of the portfolio by trading the<br />

underlying <strong>as</strong>sets. Therefore, the SPV does not issue tr<strong>an</strong>ched CLNs b<strong>as</strong>ed on the static<br />

underlying <strong>as</strong>set pool. It rather issues tr<strong>an</strong>ched CLNs referring to <strong>an</strong> actively m<strong>an</strong>aged<br />

<strong>as</strong>set pool, which is marked to market periodically (daily or weekly). Investors in different<br />

tr<strong>an</strong>ches have to absorb default related losses in reverse order of seniority. Within a market<br />

value structure, the investor is exposed to both credit risk <strong>an</strong>d the trading strategy of the<br />

portfolio m<strong>an</strong>ager. These structures are generally used for CBOs.<br />

3.9 CDS Indices<br />

The formerly competing two major families of CDS indices, the TRAC-X <strong>an</strong>d the iBoxx,<br />

beg<strong>an</strong> trading a few years ago <strong>an</strong>d merged in 2004 to one index family. The CDS indices are<br />

supported by licensed market makers. For names from North America <strong>an</strong>d the emerging<br />

markets, the indices are denoted by DJ CDX <strong>an</strong>d for Europe <strong>an</strong>d Asia by iTraxx 38 . The<br />

broadest <strong>an</strong>d most actively traded investment-grade indices are the CDX.NA.IG for North<br />

America <strong>an</strong>d the iTraxx Europe for Europe. Both contain 125 equally weighted names.<br />

Besides the geographical segmentation of the indices, the broad market indices are also<br />

segmented by credit quality (for example investment-grade, high yield), by sector (for<br />

example fin<strong>an</strong>cials, consumers, industrials, etc.) <strong>an</strong>d by maturity (for example 5 years, 10<br />

years).<br />

All indices have in common that they include large, liquid reference entities in partic-<br />

ular market segments. At the moment, these indices are traded OTC in either funded (<strong>as</strong><br />

CLNs) or unfunded form (<strong>as</strong> credit derivatives).<br />

Several CDS indices are available in tr<strong>an</strong>ched form, where every tr<strong>an</strong>che is related to<br />

a specific segment of default related losses, comparable to CDO tr<strong>an</strong>ches.<br />

For a better underst<strong>an</strong>ding we will explain the functionality of CDS indices in detail.<br />

This is done exemplarily for the iTraxx indices in the next section. Thereafter, we will<br />

briefly describe the DJ CDX indices <strong>as</strong> the functionality is rather similar.<br />

37 A c<strong>as</strong>h flow structure is described in Sections 3.8.1 <strong>an</strong>d 3.8.2.<br />

38 Up to series 2, the names of the iTraxx indices had the word ”DJ” at their beginning, for example DJ<br />

iTraxx Europe.<br />

50


3.9.1 iTraxx Indices<br />

CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

The iTraxx indices are owned, m<strong>an</strong>aged <strong>an</strong>d published by the International Index Com-<br />

p<strong>an</strong>y Limited (IIC). IIC considers itself <strong>as</strong> independent index provider aiming at improve-<br />

ment of market efficiency <strong>an</strong>d tr<strong>an</strong>sparent markets. 39 Guar<strong>an</strong>teeing for the independence,<br />

a broad shareholder b<strong>as</strong>e is necessary. 40<br />

In the following, we have a closer look at the iTraxx index family, in particular the<br />

iTraxx Europe. As already mentioned, the iTraxx index family covers the regions Europe<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Asia. For the Asi<strong>an</strong> segment, there is the iTraxx Asia with its sub-indices iTraxx<br />

Australia, iTraxx Jap<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d iTraxx Asia ex-Jap<strong>an</strong>.<br />

Composition of the iTraxx Europe The structure of the Europe<strong>an</strong> index family is<br />

shown in Figure 3.7. 41<br />

Figure 3.7: iTraxx Europe index family<br />

The Europe<strong>an</strong> index family c<strong>an</strong> be categorised according to benchmark indices, sector<br />

indices <strong>an</strong>d derivatives. Within the benchmark indices, the iTraxx Europe is the m<strong>as</strong>ter<br />

index being composed of the the so-called iTraxx Sector Indices <strong>as</strong> displayed in Table 3.1.<br />

One more sector index exists, the iTraxx Subordinated Fin<strong>an</strong>cials. It is composed<br />

of the same reference entities <strong>as</strong> the iTraxx Senior Fin<strong>an</strong>cials but containing lower rated<br />

CDS.<br />

There is a further benchmark index <strong>an</strong>d sub-index of the DJ iTraxx Europe – the iTraxx<br />

Europe HiVol, containing the 30 entities from the iTraxx Europe non-fin<strong>an</strong>cials index with<br />

the widest 5-year CDS spreads. Moreover, we see the iTraxx Europe Crossover, containing<br />

39 See [Itr06a], p. 28.<br />

40 Shareholders are ABN Amro, Barclays Capital, BNP Parib<strong>as</strong>, Deutsche B<strong>an</strong>k, Deutsche Börse, Dresdner<br />

Kleinwort, Goldm<strong>an</strong> Sachs, HSBC, JP Morg<strong>an</strong>, Morg<strong>an</strong> St<strong>an</strong>ley, UBS Investment B<strong>an</strong>k. (See website<br />

www.itraxx.com).<br />

41 Inspired by [Itr06a], p. 6.<br />

51


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

Non-Fin<strong>an</strong>cials 100 entities Fin<strong>an</strong>cials 25 entities<br />

Autos 10 Fin<strong>an</strong>cials Senior 25<br />

Consumers 30<br />

Energy 20<br />

Industrials 20<br />

Telecom, Media, Technology (TMT) 20<br />

Table 3.1: iTraxx Europe by industrial sectors<br />

the most liquid 45 non-fin<strong>an</strong>cial entities with a rating not better th<strong>an</strong> BBB- (in S&P<br />

cl<strong>as</strong>sification or <strong>an</strong> equivalent rating from <strong>an</strong>other rating agency), a negative outlook, <strong>an</strong>d<br />

with more th<strong>an</strong> EUR 100 million publicly traded debt. Besides, there exist more products.<br />

first-to-default b<strong>as</strong>kets are available for the single sectors, but also in the categories HiVol,<br />

Crossover <strong>an</strong>d Diversified. The latter contains one reference entity of each sector.<br />

Finally there are derivatives of the iTraxx indices. The iTraxx Europe is available in<br />

five st<strong>an</strong>dard tr<strong>an</strong>ches: 0-3%, 3-6%, 6-9%, 9-12% <strong>an</strong>d 12-22%, where the 0-3% tr<strong>an</strong>che<br />

is to absorb the first 3% of default related losses in the pool of reference entities (equity<br />

tr<strong>an</strong>che), the 3-6% tr<strong>an</strong>che absorbs the losses from 3% to 6% etc.. Investors c<strong>an</strong> buy<br />

iTraxx options on the spread movement of iTraxx indices. And in the future, it is pl<strong>an</strong>ned<br />

to introduce iTraxx futures contracts to trade exposure in the iTraxx Europe.<br />

Rules-b<strong>as</strong>ed Process All index series are constructed according to a rules-b<strong>as</strong>ed process,<br />

which is described in the following paragraph. At first, we introduce general rules. The<br />

roll date for each index is the 20 th of March <strong>an</strong>d the 20 th of September. New indices<br />

start on the roll date or the following business day if the roll date is not a business day.<br />

iTraxx Europe <strong>an</strong>d iTraxx HiVol have maturities of 3, 5, 7 <strong>an</strong>d 10 years, while the iTraxx<br />

Crossover <strong>an</strong>d the iTraxx Sector Indices are traded with maturities 5 <strong>an</strong>d 10 years. The<br />

maturity date for the March roll is always the 20 th of June <strong>an</strong>d for the September roll it<br />

is the 20 th of December.<br />

The reference entities in every index are equally weighted. Weighting adjustments<br />

(+/ − 0.01%) are made in alphabetical order if the number of index components c<strong>an</strong>not<br />

be divided equally to two decimal places. 42<br />

Now, we explain the index rules exemplarily for the iTraxx Europe. This index is<br />

composed of the 125 most liquid CDS of investment-grade rated Europe<strong>an</strong> reference enti-<br />

ties with respect to the previous six months, following dealer liquidity polls. Each market<br />

maker h<strong>as</strong> to submit a list of 200 to 250 reference entities b<strong>as</strong>ed on the following criteria:<br />

• The reference entity is incorporated in Europe.<br />

• The listed names had the highest CDS trading volume over the previous 6 months.<br />

• The market maker’s internal tr<strong>an</strong>sactions are excluded from the volume statistics.<br />

• If several CDS of one reference entity are traded, the total volume of one name is<br />

calculated <strong>as</strong> sum of the single trading volumes.<br />

42 See [Itr06b], p. 3.<br />

52


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

We denote the consolidated list of all market makers, which is sorted by liquidity of the<br />

reference entity, <strong>as</strong> m<strong>as</strong>ter list.<br />

ria: 43<br />

IIC then determines the members of the new indices according to the following crite-<br />

• Each entity h<strong>as</strong> to be rated investment-grade by Fitch, Moody’s or S&P. If <strong>an</strong> entity<br />

h<strong>as</strong> several ratings, the lowest rating is considered.<br />

• The remaining entities are <strong>as</strong>signed to their appropriate iTraxx sector (<strong>as</strong> listed in<br />

Table 3.1) <strong>an</strong>d then r<strong>an</strong>ked within the sector according to the liquidity r<strong>an</strong>king of<br />

the market makers. The remaining list is denoted by sector list <strong>an</strong>d is part of the<br />

overall m<strong>as</strong>ter list.<br />

• At the beginning, the index composition is set to be the same <strong>as</strong> the previous series.<br />

• Entities that defaulted, ch<strong>an</strong>ged sector, merged or were downgraded are excluded<br />

from the index. Entities r<strong>an</strong>king in the top 50% of the number of entities in a sector<br />

list that are not yet in the index are added to the index. 44 Entities in the index<br />

with a lower r<strong>an</strong>k th<strong>an</strong> 125% of the predetermined number of entities in a sector, i.e.<br />

in the c<strong>as</strong>e of the energy sector r<strong>an</strong>ked lower th<strong>an</strong> 25 <strong>as</strong> the predetermined number<br />

is 20, are eliminated <strong>an</strong>d replaced by the next liquid entity not yet in the index.<br />

Entities r<strong>an</strong>ked below 150 in the overall m<strong>as</strong>ter list are removed from the index <strong>an</strong>d<br />

replaced by the most liquid entity in this sector which is not yet in the index, unless<br />

the potential entity is not less liquid.<br />

• The iTraxx Europe comprises 125 reference entities which are selected according to<br />

the highest r<strong>an</strong>ks in each sector. The sector weights are given in Table 3.1. The<br />

names in the index are all equally weighted with 1<br />

125<br />

or 0.8%.<br />

Every index h<strong>as</strong> a fixed spread, which represents a kind of average spread of all reference<br />

entities. Analogously, every index h<strong>as</strong> a fixed recovery rate in the c<strong>as</strong>e of default of a<br />

reference entity, independent from the actual recovery rate. Both, the fixed spread <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the fixed recovery rate, are determined after having agreed upon the composition of the<br />

new index series. Then, IIC initiates a telephone poll with all market makers to determine<br />

the fixed spread of each index <strong>an</strong>d the recovery rates. The market makers quote a spread<br />

for every index. The spread which is accepted by a majority of the participating market<br />

makers is rounded to the nearest 5 bps. Recovery rates are determined <strong>an</strong>alogously, but<br />

rounded to the nearest 5%. 45<br />

Considering tr<strong>an</strong>ched iTraxx Europe indices, the fixed spread for each tr<strong>an</strong>che within<br />

one series is determined at inception <strong>an</strong>alogous to the process for untr<strong>an</strong>ched indices.<br />

43<br />

We enumerate the most import<strong>an</strong>t criteria. There are some more which c<strong>an</strong> be found in [Itr06b], pp.<br />

4-5.<br />

44If<br />

for example a reference entity of the energy sector is r<strong>an</strong>ked in the top 10 in the sector list, but it is<br />

not in the index, it is included. At the same time, the lowest r<strong>an</strong>king entity in this sector list is eliminated<br />

from the index.<br />

45<br />

For more information regarding the coupons <strong>an</strong>d recovery rates for the series 6, we refer to paragraph<br />

”History” in this section.<br />

53


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

Trading iTraxx Indices There are two ways of trading iTraxx indices – unfunded or<br />

funded. Trading the index in a funded way, the protection seller (investor) buys a FRN,<br />

which pays a coupon of the 3 month LIBOR plus the fixed index spread quarterly. If no<br />

credit event occurs, the coupon is paid until maturity. Then, the investor receives the<br />

notional amount of the FRN. However, if a credit event of a reference entity takes place,<br />

the protection seller receives the recovery value but the notional amount of the FRN is<br />

reduced according to the weight of the reference entity (for example from 100% to 99.2%)<br />

<strong>an</strong>d future coupon payments are b<strong>as</strong>ed on the new notional amount. Though, the coupon<br />

rate remains unch<strong>an</strong>ged.<br />

Trading the index in <strong>an</strong> unfunded way, the protection seller receives the quarterly<br />

spread premium determined at inception. In c<strong>as</strong>e of no credit event, the c<strong>as</strong>h flows remain<br />

the same until maturity. If, however, a credit event occurs, the default related loss is<br />

settled physically. Then, the protection buyer delivers bonds issued by the reference<br />

entity, amounting to the weight of the defaulted reference entity in the index (for example<br />

0.8%) multiplied by the notional amount of the contract between the involved parties. In<br />

return, he receives the nominal value of the bonds. Afterwards, the nominal value of the<br />

contract between protection seller <strong>an</strong>d protection buyer is reduced accordingly while the<br />

spread premium (in bps) remains unch<strong>an</strong>ged.<br />

During the term of a series, the development of the quoted spread depends on supply<br />

<strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d, while the fixed spread for the series remains the same. Therefore, a compen-<br />

sation for the difference between the quoted <strong>an</strong>d the fixed spread h<strong>as</strong> to take place. We<br />

w<strong>an</strong>t to explain this fact with <strong>an</strong> example. 46<br />

Let us <strong>as</strong>sume <strong>an</strong> investor who w<strong>an</strong>ts to act <strong>as</strong> protection seller in <strong>an</strong> unfunded CDS<br />

index with a notional amount of EUR 10,000,000 at t. Let the fixed spread for the series<br />

be 30 bps <strong>an</strong>d the quoted spread 28 bps at t. Then, the protection seller h<strong>as</strong> to pay the<br />

present value of 2 bps for the remaining term of the CDS index to the protection buyer. In<br />

return, he receives 30 bps per <strong>an</strong>num quarterly on the notional amount. If, on the other<br />

h<strong>an</strong>d, the quoted spread is higher th<strong>an</strong> 30 bps, say 31 bps, the protection buyer h<strong>as</strong> to pay<br />

the present value of 1 bp for the remaining term of the CDS index to the protection seller.<br />

Furthermore, the protection seller receives 30 bps per <strong>an</strong>num quarterly on the notional<br />

amount from the protection buyer for the remaining term of the CDS index.<br />

Regarding tr<strong>an</strong>ched iTraxx Europe CDS indices, market makers also quote daily spreads<br />

for the tr<strong>an</strong>ches. In addition, the investor of the equity tr<strong>an</strong>che receives <strong>an</strong> upfront payment<br />

which is quoted in the market <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>nual spread of 500 bps (i.e. 125 bps quarterly).<br />

History The first series w<strong>as</strong> launched at the 21 st of June, 2004, <strong>an</strong>d the second at the<br />

20 th of September, 2004. Since then, every six months (at the 20 th of March <strong>an</strong>d at the<br />

20 th of September), a new series of iTraxx Europe h<strong>as</strong> been issued. Table 3.2 gives <strong>an</strong><br />

overview over the issu<strong>an</strong>ces.<br />

Exemplarily for the iTraxx Europe series 6, we show the fixed spread for the different<br />

maturities <strong>an</strong>d the recovery rates. This is done in Table 3.3. 47<br />

We see <strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>ing fixed spread with longer maturities. The recovery rate is 40% for<br />

46 See [Itr06a], p. 14.<br />

47 See [Itr06a], p. 26.<br />

54


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

Series Issu<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

1 21.06.2004<br />

2 20.09.2004<br />

3 21.03.2005<br />

4 20.09.2005<br />

5 20.03.2006<br />

6 20.09.2006<br />

Table 3.2: Issu<strong>an</strong>ce of iTraxx Europe series<br />

Term in years Maturity Fixed Spread Recovery Rate<br />

3 20.12.2009 20 40%<br />

5 20.12.2011 30 40%<br />

7 20.12.2013 40 40%<br />

10 20.12.2016 50 40%<br />

Table 3.3: Fixed spreads <strong>an</strong>d recovery rates of iTraxx Europe series 6<br />

all maturities. A recovery rate of 40%, however, is not given for all iTraxx indices. The<br />

iTraxx Subordinated Fin<strong>an</strong>cials of the series 6, for example, h<strong>as</strong> a recovery rate of 20%. 48<br />

Figure (3.8) gives <strong>an</strong> impression of the spread history of the iTraxx Europe with a 5<br />

years term at issu<strong>an</strong>ce. We take this term <strong>as</strong> it is the most liquid index. 49<br />

Figure 3.8: Spread history iTraxx Europe, 5 years term<br />

From the figure, we observe a term structure of the quoted spreads. It becomes obvious<br />

that a new series always starts with a higher spread th<strong>an</strong> a previous series, i.e. the quoted<br />

48 See [Itr06a] p. 26.<br />

49 The data is taken from Bloomberg. The ticker symbols are ITRXEB51 Curncy, ITRXEB52 Curncy,<br />

ITRXEB53 Curncy, ITRXEB54 Curncy, ITRXEB55 Curncy <strong>an</strong>d ITRXEB56 Curncy, where the first number<br />

denotes the term in years at issu<strong>an</strong>ce (here 5), <strong>an</strong>d the l<strong>as</strong>t number indicates the number of the<br />

series.<br />

55


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

spread is lower for a series with a lower remaining time until maturity.<br />

Furthermore, we observe one period that is very striking. In spring 2005, the Americ<strong>an</strong><br />

car producers General Motors <strong>an</strong>d Ford were in a deep crisis. After <strong>an</strong>nouncing high<br />

losses <strong>an</strong>d negative future outlooks, their bonds were downgraded to non-investment-grade<br />

bonds. This development w<strong>as</strong> also <strong>an</strong>ticipated by CDS indices.<br />

3.9.2 DJ CDX Indices<br />

As already mentioned, we briefly describe the DJ CDX indices since their functionality is<br />

rather similar to the iTraxx indices. The DJ CDX indices cover the regions North America<br />

<strong>an</strong>d emerging markets. Table 3.4 gives <strong>an</strong> overview on DJ CDX indices.<br />

Index No. of entities Characteristics<br />

DJ CDX.NA.IG 125 Investment-grade reference entities,<br />

domiciled in North America<br />

DJ CDX.NA.IG.HVOL 30 Investment-grade reference entities<br />

with a wide CDS spread, domiciled<br />

in North America<br />

DJ CDX.NA.XO 35 Rating BBB or BB (in S&P cl<strong>as</strong>sification<br />

or <strong>an</strong> equivalent rating from<br />

<strong>an</strong>other rating agency), entities that<br />

are domiciled in North America or<br />

have a majority of their outst<strong>an</strong>ding<br />

bonds <strong>an</strong>d lo<strong>an</strong>s denominated in<br />

USD<br />

DJ CDX.NA.HY 100 Non-investment-grade<br />

domiciled in North America<br />

entities<br />

DJ CDX.NA.EM 14 Sovereign issuers from three regions<br />

(Latin America; E<strong>as</strong>tern Europe,<br />

the Middle E<strong>as</strong>t <strong>an</strong>d Africa; Asia)<br />

DJ CDX.NA.EM.DI-<br />

VERSIFIED<br />

40 Sovereign <strong>an</strong>d corporate issuers<br />

from three regions (Latin America;<br />

E<strong>as</strong>tern Europe, the Middle E<strong>as</strong>t<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Africa; Asia)<br />

Table 3.4: DJ CDX Indices<br />

Analogous to the iTraxx Europe, the DJ CDX.NA.IG h<strong>as</strong> several sub-indices: DJ CDX<br />

IG Consumer, DJ CDX IG Energy, DJ CDX IG Fin<strong>an</strong>cials, DJ CDX IG HighVol, DJ CDX<br />

IG Industrials, DJ CDX IG TMT. Like the iTraxx indices, the DJ CDX indices are also<br />

composed of equally weighted reference entities.<br />

The CDX.NA.IG is available in five tr<strong>an</strong>ches which are slightly different from the<br />

iTraxx Europe tr<strong>an</strong>ches. They comprise 0-3% (equity tr<strong>an</strong>che), 3-7%, 7-10%, 10-15% <strong>an</strong>d<br />

15-30%.<br />

We do not w<strong>an</strong>t to describe the rules for constructing the DJ CDX indices <strong>as</strong> they are<br />

similar to the iTraxx construction rules. But we refer the interested reader to [Dow05].<br />

However, we give <strong>an</strong> impression of the spread history of the DJ CDX.NA.IG indices.<br />

This is shown in Figure 3.9. We also take the DJ CDX.NA.IG with a 5 years term at<br />

issu<strong>an</strong>ce. 50<br />

50 The data is taken from JP Morg<strong>an</strong> Portal <strong>an</strong>d represents the DJ CDX.NA.IG mid spread quoted by<br />

56


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

Figure 3.9: Spread history DJ CDX.NA.IG, 5 years term<br />

From this figure, the term structure is not that obvious. We c<strong>an</strong> see that series 3 <strong>an</strong>d<br />

4 have the same level at issu<strong>an</strong>ce of series 4. Series 5 even starts with a lower spread,<br />

which might be <strong>as</strong>signed to a new index composition with higher rated CDS. At issu<strong>an</strong>ce,<br />

series 6 starts with a higher spread th<strong>an</strong> series 5 h<strong>as</strong> at that date. This is what we saw for<br />

every series in the iTraxx Europe. In Spring 2005, we observe again the crisis of General<br />

Motors <strong>an</strong>d Ford.<br />

3.9.3 Motivations for Investors<br />

Compared to single credit derivative contracts, CDS indices offer several adv<strong>an</strong>tages, that<br />

fuelled the growth of the market. 51<br />

• They provide narrow bid-<strong>as</strong>k-spreads. 52<br />

• They provide a diversified credit risk exposure in one single tr<strong>an</strong>saction.<br />

• Formerly, the CDS market w<strong>as</strong> mainly <strong>an</strong> interb<strong>an</strong>k market. By the introduction of<br />

CDS indices, however, investors who were formerly excluded from that market are<br />

now more e<strong>as</strong>ily able to take part in it.<br />

• They facilitate the implementation of investment, hedging <strong>an</strong>d trading strategies in<br />

the field of credit risk.<br />

JPMorg<strong>an</strong>.<br />

51<br />

For more information regarding the size <strong>an</strong>d the evolution of the market, we refer to Section 2.3.6,<br />

paragraph market breakdown by instrument.<br />

52<br />

The bid-<strong>as</strong>k-spread for the iTraxx Europe with a maturity of 5 years within one year w<strong>as</strong> approximately<br />

0.6 bps, for 10 years approximately 1.1 bps, for 3 years approximately 1.5 bps <strong>an</strong>d for 7 years approximately<br />

1.6 bps.<br />

57


CHAPTER 3. CREDIT RISK TRANSFER INSTRUMENTS<br />

• They help that the credit market have become more liquid, efficient <strong>an</strong>d tr<strong>an</strong>sparent.<br />

• The sectoral sub-indices c<strong>an</strong> be used to limit or to extend credit risk exposure towards<br />

a certain industry.<br />

Therefore, in the me<strong>an</strong>time CDS indices provide a st<strong>an</strong>dard benchmark in the credit<br />

market.<br />

3.9.4 Market Particip<strong>an</strong>ts<br />

The main market particip<strong>an</strong>ts are <strong>as</strong>set m<strong>an</strong>agers, hedge funds, insur<strong>an</strong>ce comp<strong>an</strong>ies,<br />

corporate tre<strong>as</strong>ury <strong>an</strong>d b<strong>an</strong>k proprietary desks.<br />

The <strong>as</strong>set m<strong>an</strong>agers try to diversify their portfolio by adding credit risk. Moreover,<br />

they regard the CDS indices <strong>as</strong> hedging tools.<br />

Hedge funds often w<strong>an</strong>t to implement relative value trading, for example name vs.<br />

sector, sector vs. sector, sector vs. benchmark. This c<strong>an</strong> be realised by CDS indices.<br />

Generally, the sector indices c<strong>an</strong> represent a hedging tool for corporates, if they are<br />

exposed to the credit risk of one br<strong>an</strong>che in particular. Furthermore, CDS indices give<br />

access to diversified credit risk. Adding CDS indices to a portfolio c<strong>an</strong> be re<strong>as</strong>onable from<br />

<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set allocation perspective.<br />

For b<strong>an</strong>ks, CDS indices allow for a better m<strong>an</strong>agement of credit risk. In addition, the<br />

indices are also used to bet on credit views.<br />

So far, we learned a lot about credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer <strong>an</strong>d the respective instruments in<br />

theory. In the following chapter, we <strong>an</strong>alyse return data to better underst<strong>an</strong>d the distinct<br />

return properties of credit instruments.<br />

58


Chapter 4<br />

Data Analysis<br />

In this chapter, we aim at giving <strong>an</strong> idea of distributional properties of credit instruments.<br />

The <strong>an</strong>alyses are exemplarily done for returns of Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates.<br />

We <strong>an</strong>alyse the Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates for the United States in Section 4.2 <strong>an</strong>d for<br />

the Euro-zone in Section 4.3. The US aggregate index 1 covers the USD-denominated,<br />

investment-grade, fixed-rate, taxable bond market, while the Euro-aggregate index 2 tracks<br />

Euro-denominated, investment-grade, fixed-rate securities. Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates are con-<br />

sidered <strong>as</strong> representatives for credit instruments in general, since they are portfolios of<br />

credit instruments <strong>an</strong>d since the data is e<strong>as</strong>ily accessible. 3 We are particularly interested,<br />

whether the return distributions follow a normal distribution, because the <strong>as</strong>sumption of<br />

normally distributed returns is often made to facilitate portfolio selection. 4 If the <strong>as</strong>-<br />

sumption does not hold true, the optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocation, however, is not more th<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong><br />

approximation <strong>an</strong>d other selection criteria are more appropriate.<br />

For our further <strong>an</strong>alyses we use discrete daily return data. Though, before <strong>an</strong>alysing<br />

the data, we make a few remarks on return definitions in Section 4.1.<br />

4.1 A Note on Return Definitions<br />

Return is a very import<strong>an</strong>t concept in fin<strong>an</strong>cial modelling. There are different ways to de-<br />

fine return. We introduce the concept of simple or discrete returns <strong>an</strong>d of log or continuous<br />

returns. 5<br />

1<br />

See [Leh06], p. 174.<br />

2<br />

See [Leh06], p. 200.<br />

3<br />

The data is e<strong>as</strong>ily available on the Lehm<strong>an</strong> Brothers Lehm<strong>an</strong> Live Portal (www.lehm<strong>an</strong>live.com). In<br />

contr<strong>as</strong>t, for m<strong>an</strong>y credit instruments, such <strong>as</strong> CDS indices, there is no return data available. Provider<br />

such <strong>as</strong> Bloomberg only provide quoted CDS index spreads (see Figures 3.8 <strong>an</strong>d 3.9). Spreads alone,<br />

however, do no not allow to make return calculations (The return components of (funded) CDS <strong>an</strong>d CDS<br />

indices, <strong>as</strong> well <strong>as</strong> their pricing is explained in Sections 5.5.5 <strong>an</strong>d 5.5.6.). For example, we do not have<br />

information about defaults, which obviously have a signific<strong>an</strong>t influence on the return of a CDS index.<br />

Furthermore, there are new series twice a year, with the latest series being the most liquid one. For this<br />

re<strong>as</strong>on, considering the return of a certain index series entails a distortion, due to a lower liquidity 6 months<br />

after issu<strong>an</strong>ce. All these facts prevent us from re<strong>as</strong>onably calculating the returns of CDS indices.<br />

4<br />

For more background regarding portfolio selection <strong>an</strong>d various selection criteria, we refer the reader<br />

to Chapter 6.<br />

5<br />

[Dor02] provide <strong>an</strong> extensive discussion of dealing with the application of discrete <strong>an</strong>d continuous<br />

returns.<br />

59


Definition 4.1 (Simple Return)<br />

CHAPTER 4. DATA ANALYSIS<br />

Let the price of <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set or <strong>an</strong> index at time t denote by Pt. Then, the simple or discrete<br />

return between the dates t − 1 <strong>an</strong>d t is defined by<br />

Rt = Pt<br />

− 1. (4.1)<br />

Pt−1<br />

Let us <strong>as</strong>sume, that there are n <strong>as</strong>sets to invest in with returns Ri,t, i = 1, ..., n <strong>an</strong>d<br />

let xi be the portfolio weight of <strong>as</strong>set i with<br />

n�<br />

xi = 1. (4.2)<br />

i=1<br />

Then, we denote the portfolio by x := (x1, ..., xn) T , <strong>an</strong>d we calculate the simple return of<br />

a portfolio of n <strong>as</strong>sets according to<br />

Rt(x) =<br />

n�<br />

i=1<br />

xiRi,t<br />

(4.3)<br />

From this equation, it becomes obvious that the linear relationship allows for a simple<br />

return calculation in a portfolio context.<br />

Definition 4.2 (Log Return)<br />

Let the price of <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set or <strong>an</strong> index at time t denote by Pt. Then, the log or continuous<br />

return between the dates t − 1 <strong>an</strong>d t is defined by<br />

� �<br />

Pt<br />

rt = ln = ln (1 + Rt) . (4.4)<br />

Pt−1<br />

In equation (4.4) we have already seen that we c<strong>an</strong> express the log return in terms<br />

of a discrete return. Rewriting the equation, the discrete return in terms of log return is<br />

calculated by<br />

Rt = exp (rt) − 1. (4.5)<br />

The main difference between simple returns <strong>an</strong>d log returns is their domain. Log<br />

returns rt c<strong>an</strong> attain values in R, while simple returns Rt c<strong>an</strong> only have values between<br />

[−1, ∞). The approximation errors between log <strong>an</strong>d simple returns are negligible when<br />

short periods of time are considered. 6<br />

According to Dorfleitner, simple returns are to use in a portfolio context 7 . That is<br />

why we use discrete returns for return calculations of single instruments <strong>an</strong>d of portfolios.<br />

In the following, we will use the term ”return” for a simple return. If we use a log return,<br />

we will write ”log return”.<br />

4.2 US Aggregates<br />

At first, we <strong>an</strong>alyse daily discrete returns of the US Lehm<strong>an</strong> Brothers aggregates listed in<br />

Table 4.1.<br />

6 See [Dor02], p. 4.<br />

7 See [Dor02], p. 20.<br />

60


CHAPTER 4. DATA ANALYSIS<br />

Aggregate Name Period Time Series No. of Issuers per<br />

29.09.2006<br />

US Aggregate: Aaa 07.11.2002 – 29.09.2006 3560<br />

US Aggregate: Aa 07.11.2002 – 29.09.2006 759<br />

US Aggregate: A 07.11.2002 – 29.09.2006 1404<br />

US Aggregate: Baa 07.11.2002 – 29.09.2006 1215<br />

US Aggregate: Corporates 07.11.2002 – 29.09.2006 2721<br />

Table 4.1: US Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates<br />

An e<strong>as</strong>y way to compare the sample distribution to the normal distribution 8 is a<br />

qu<strong>an</strong>tile-qu<strong>an</strong>tile plot (QQ-plot) which is shown in Figure 4.1 for all considered US ag-<br />

gregates. There, the empirical returns are plotted against the theoretical qu<strong>an</strong>tiles, in<br />

this c<strong>as</strong>e the qu<strong>an</strong>tiles of a normal distribution. 9 If the data points build a line, we c<strong>an</strong><br />

conclude that the empirical <strong>an</strong>d the theoretical distributions are the same. However, if<br />

there are signific<strong>an</strong>t deviations from the theoretical distribution, this is <strong>an</strong> indication for<br />

a different empirical distribution.<br />

Figure 4.1: QQ-plots of US aggregates<br />

This figure indicates a potential non-normality of the return data, <strong>as</strong> the tails signifi-<br />

c<strong>an</strong>tly deviate from the theoretical qu<strong>an</strong>tiles.<br />

Figure 4.2 shows the histograms for the US aggregates <strong>an</strong>d the density of the normal<br />

distribution (solid line) having the same me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation <strong>as</strong> the data.<br />

Also here, we have the impression that the returns do not exactly follow a normal<br />

distribution. The empirical distribution seems to be fat tailed.<br />

8 Formally, the normal distribution is given in Definition 5.16.<br />

9 For more background regarding QQ-plots, we refer for example to [Har95], pp. 847-849.<br />

61


Figure 4.2: Histogram of US aggregates<br />

CHAPTER 4. DATA ANALYSIS<br />

Although graphical examination of data is a useful tool for becoming aware of de-<br />

viations from normality, it is too imprecise for statistical inference. In order to obtain<br />

statistically signific<strong>an</strong>t statements on the return distributions, we perform the Jarque-<br />

Bera test 10 for normality.<br />

Definition 4.3 (Jarque-Bera Test for Normality)<br />

Let be X1, ..., Xm r<strong>an</strong>dom variables with sample me<strong>an</strong><br />

¯X = 1<br />

m<br />

m�<br />

Xi. (4.6)<br />

i=1<br />

Let Zi be the st<strong>an</strong>dardised r<strong>an</strong>dom variable defined <strong>as</strong><br />

Zi :=<br />

� 1<br />

m<br />

Xi − ¯ X<br />

� m<br />

i=1 (Xi − ¯ X) 2<br />

. (4.7)<br />

Then, the the sample skewness S(Z) <strong>an</strong>d sample excess kurtosis K excess are defined ac-<br />

cording to<br />

10 See, for example, [Gre03], p. 225.<br />

S(Z) := 1<br />

m<br />

K excess (Z) := 1<br />

m<br />

m�<br />

i=1<br />

Z 3 i , (4.8)<br />

m�<br />

Z 4 i − 3. (4.9)<br />

i=1<br />

62


<strong>an</strong>d the test statistic T is given by<br />

CHAPTER 4. DATA ANALYSIS<br />

�<br />

S(Z) 2<br />

T = m ·<br />

6 + Kexcess (Z) 2 �<br />

. (4.10)<br />

24<br />

Under the null hypothesis of normal distribution, T is <strong>as</strong>ymptotically χ 2 2 -distributed.<br />

Hence, the critical value for a signific<strong>an</strong>ce level of α = 1% is 9.2103 <strong>an</strong>d α = 5% it is<br />

5.9915.<br />

Table 4.2 summarises the results of the Jarque-Bera test.<br />

Aggregate Name m S(Z) K excess (Z) T p-value<br />

US Aggregate: Aaa 975 -0.1191 1.7622 128.46 0.00%<br />

US Aggregate: Aa 975 -0.2802 1.5500 110.36 0.00%<br />

US Aggregate: A 975 -0.1635 1.4726 92.45 0.00%<br />

US Aggregate: Baa 975 -0.0356 1.3836 78.09 0.00%<br />

US Aggregate: Corporates 975 -0.1838 1.2390 67.86 0.00%<br />

Table 4.2: Jarque-Bera test for US Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates<br />

We c<strong>an</strong> see that T is in every c<strong>as</strong>e much higher th<strong>an</strong> the critical values for α = 0.01%<br />

<strong>an</strong>d α = 0.05%. Then, the p-value 11 equals 0.00% for every aggregate, which me<strong>an</strong>s that<br />

the null hypotheses of normally distributed returns have to be rejected on a signific<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

level of α = 0.01% <strong>an</strong>d α = 0.05%, respectively. Furthermore, we observe exclusively<br />

negatively skewed return distributions.<br />

We also performed the test with log returns. 12 The result is summarised in Table 4.3.<br />

Aggregate Name T p-value<br />

US Aggregate: Aaa 129.47 0.00%<br />

US Aggregate: Aa 113.66 0.00%<br />

US Aggregate: A 94.50 0.00%<br />

US Aggregate: Baa 78.43 0.00%<br />

US Aggregate: Corporates 70.04 0.00%<br />

Table 4.3: Jarque-Bera test for US Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates (log returns)<br />

The test statistics T are even higher th<strong>an</strong> for discrete returns. Therefore, we reject the<br />

null hypotheses of normally distributed returns.<br />

4.3 Euro-Aggregates<br />

Now, we <strong>an</strong>alyse the corresponding Euro-Lehm<strong>an</strong> Brothers aggregates listed in Table 4.4<br />

<strong>an</strong>alogous to the US Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates.<br />

Both, the QQ-plots (Figure 4.3) <strong>an</strong>d the histograms (Figure 4.4) indicate a clear non-<br />

normality of the return data. Particularly the left tail seems to be heavily tailed.<br />

Therefore, we perform the Jarque-Bera test for normality, again, <strong>as</strong> defined in 4.3. So,<br />

we w<strong>an</strong>t to find statistically signific<strong>an</strong>t statements regarding the return distribution. The<br />

test results are shown in Table 4.5.<br />

11 The p-value is the the lowest signific<strong>an</strong>ce level allowing to reject the null hypothesis. Thus, a p-value<br />

lower th<strong>an</strong> the signific<strong>an</strong>ce level implies a rejection of the null hypothesis.<br />

12 See Definition 4.2.<br />

63


CHAPTER 4. DATA ANALYSIS<br />

Aggregate Name Period Time Series No. of Issuers per<br />

29.09.2006<br />

Euro-Aggregate: Aaa 03.08.1998 – 29.09.2006 1054<br />

Euro-Aggregate: Aa 03.08.1998 – 29.09.2006 690<br />

Euro-Aggregate: A 03.08.1998 – 29.09.2006 559<br />

Euro-Aggregate: Baa 03.08.1998 – 29.09.2006 279<br />

Euro-Aggregate: Corporates 03.08.1998 – 29.09.2006 1093<br />

Table 4.4: Euro-Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates<br />

Figure 4.3: QQ-plots of Euro-aggregates<br />

For the Euro-aggregates the test statistics are even higher th<strong>an</strong> for the US aggregates.<br />

The p-value is 0.00% for every aggregate. Consequently, we clearly have to reject the<br />

null hypotheses of normally distributed returns. Besides, we observe again exclusively<br />

negatively skewed return distributions.<br />

We compare the test results of discrete returns to log returns. These results are<br />

summarised in Table 4.6.<br />

Again, we see higher test statistics T for the log return <strong>an</strong>d therefore a clear evidence<br />

for non-normality of log returns.<br />

64


Figure 4.4: Histogram of Euro-aggregates<br />

CHAPTER 4. DATA ANALYSIS<br />

Aggregate Name m S(Z) K excess (Z) T p-value<br />

Euro-Aggregate: Aaa 2065 -0.5003 2.4611 607.31 0.00%<br />

Euro-Aggregate: Aa 2065 -0.4686 3.4010 1070.79 0.00%<br />

Euro-Aggregate: A 2065 -0.4752 2.0234 430.00 0.00%<br />

Euro-Aggregate: Baa 2065 -0.3132 11.5625 11228.74 0.00%<br />

Euro-Aggregate: Corporates 2065 -0.4969 2.8251 771.70 0.00%<br />

Table 4.5: Jarque-Bera test for Euro-Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates<br />

Aggregate Name T p-value<br />

Euro-Aggregate: Aaa 629.02 0.00%<br />

Euro-Aggregate: Aa 1095.21 0.00%<br />

Euro-Aggregate: A 445.17 0.00%<br />

Euro-Aggregate: Baa 11255.58 0.00%<br />

Euro-Aggregate: Corporates 800.73 0.00%<br />

Table 4.6: Jarque-Bera test for Euro-Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates (log returns)<br />

65


4.4 Summary<br />

CHAPTER 4. DATA ANALYSIS<br />

Particularly the Euro-Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates are heavily tailed in the left-h<strong>an</strong>d side of the<br />

distribution, i.e. for negative returns. This might be attributed to defaults within the<br />

aggregates. The re<strong>as</strong>on why this c<strong>an</strong> be better observed for the Euro-Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates<br />

compared to the US Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates is the aggregate size. The Europe<strong>an</strong> aggregates<br />

consist of less issuers th<strong>an</strong> the US aggregates. Therefore, a default produces more extreme<br />

returns within Europe<strong>an</strong> aggregates.<br />

We w<strong>an</strong>t to consider corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS that only have one reference entity <strong>an</strong>d<br />

CDS indices with 125 reference entities, which is still considerably lower th<strong>an</strong> the number<br />

of reference entities in the Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates. Consequently, defaults will play a more<br />

import<strong>an</strong>t role for the investment universe in this thesis resulting in even fatter left tails.<br />

To conclude, we know that in credit portfolios defaults may occur, which result in<br />

heavily tailed return distributions. In order to obtain such distributions, we use a sim-<br />

ulation approach that, on the one h<strong>an</strong>d, simulates the development of interest-rates <strong>an</strong>d<br />

credit spreads <strong>an</strong>d, on the other h<strong>an</strong>d, default times for issuers with different ratings. This<br />

approach is introduced in Chapter 5.<br />

66


Chapter 5<br />

Simulation <strong>an</strong>d Pricing Framework<br />

The previous chapters pointed out that returns of credit instruments are not normally dis-<br />

tributed. This fact c<strong>an</strong> partly be attributed to a positive probability of default for several<br />

instruments. In order to take into account these distinct characteristics, we introduce a<br />

simulation <strong>an</strong>d pricing framework in this chapter.<br />

First, we explain some import<strong>an</strong>t <strong>as</strong>pects of interest-rate modelling in Section 5.1,<br />

which build a b<strong>as</strong>is for the following sections in this chapter. In Section 5.2, we introduce<br />

the model of Zagst, which is used to simulate zero-rates, credit spreads for several rating<br />

cl<strong>as</strong>ses, a CDS index spread <strong>an</strong>d the return of <strong>an</strong> equity index. Section 5.3 briefly illus-<br />

trates <strong>an</strong> approach going back to Nelson-Siegel to describe a complete interest-rate curve<br />

with only four parameters. This approach is used to fit the model interest-rate curve to the<br />

actual interest-rate curve at simulation start date. To take into account the distinct return<br />

characteristics of credit instruments, we simulate correlated default times. We describe the<br />

procedure in Section 5.4: For the simulation, we use the popular one-factor copula model,<br />

which is described in Section 5.4.2. This model is used not only for Gaussi<strong>an</strong> one-factor<br />

copula, but also for Normal Inverse Gaussi<strong>an</strong> one-factor copula, since the latter is able to<br />

produce more realistic properties of default times. In order to determine the correlated<br />

default times, it is necessary to know their distribution function, which is calculated with<br />

migration matrices. The procedure c<strong>an</strong> be found in Section 5.4.1. The l<strong>as</strong>t section intro-<br />

duces the pricing framework. We price zero-coupon bonds <strong>an</strong>d coupon bonds issued by a<br />

sovereign or a corporation. Furthermore, we price funded CDS <strong>an</strong>d funded CDS indices,<br />

applying the const<strong>an</strong>t default intensity model for expected loss calculations.<br />

5.1 A Note on Interest-Rate Modelling<br />

In this section we give a brief introduction in interest-rate modelling. We follow primarily<br />

[Zag02]. 1<br />

It is obvious that getting one Euro today is better th<strong>an</strong> getting one Euro in the future.<br />

But what should be paid today or at time t for a guar<strong>an</strong>teed payment of one Euro at<br />

time T , T ≥ t? This question is <strong>an</strong>swered by a zero-coupon bond <strong>as</strong> already described<br />

in Section 2.2.2. Before defining this product formally, we need to introduce a formal<br />

definition of interest-rates.<br />

1 For more theoretical background regarding interest-rate modelling, we refer for example to [Zag02].<br />

67


Definition 5.1 (Interest-Rate)<br />

CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

An interest-rate (also spot rate or zero rate) R(t, T ) denotes a guar<strong>an</strong>teed growth of<br />

one unit of money at time t for the period [t,T]. There are different kinds of interest rates:<br />

(a) A linear interest-rate Rl(t, T ) is given, if the growth of one unit of money at time<br />

t to time T is computed <strong>as</strong> 1 + Rl(t, T )(T − t).<br />

(b) A discrete interest-rate Rd(t, T ) is given, if the growth of one unit of money at time<br />

t to time T is computed <strong>as</strong> [1 + Rd(t, T )] (T −t) .<br />

(c) A continuous interest-rate Rc(t, T ) is given, if the growth of one unit of money at<br />

time t to time T is computed <strong>as</strong> exp(Rc(t, T )(T − t)).<br />

As a convention, we will use continuous interest-rates throughout the thesis, if not<br />

stated otherwise <strong>an</strong>d denote them by R(t, T ) = Rc(t, T ).<br />

Definition 5.2 (Interest-Rate Curve)<br />

The mapping T → R(t, T ) is called interest-rate curve at time t (T > t).<br />

Interest-rate curves c<strong>an</strong> take different forms. Most often, we see incre<strong>as</strong>ing (normal)<br />

interest-rate curves, but there are also falling (inverse) interest-rate curves or interest-rate<br />

curves ch<strong>an</strong>ging their sign of the slope.<br />

bond.<br />

Having defined the interest-rate curve, we c<strong>an</strong> give a formal definition of a zero-coupon<br />

Definition 5.3 (Zero-Coupon Bond)<br />

A zero-coupon bond is a fin<strong>an</strong>cial contract which guar<strong>an</strong>tees the payment of a nominal<br />

amount L at maturity T . Then, using Definition 5.1, the price of a zero-coupon bond<br />

P (t, T ) at time t ≤ T is given by<br />

P (t, T ) is also denoted by discount factor, if L=1.<br />

Remark 5.4<br />

P (t, T ) = L · exp(−R(t, T )(T − t)). (5.1)<br />

In the following we make a few remarks regarding zero-coupon bonds.<br />

(a) In the following, we <strong>as</strong>sume the notional amount L to equal one, if we do not mention<br />

<strong>an</strong>ything else.<br />

(b) Definition 5.3 <strong>as</strong>sumes the payment of the notional amount to be certain <strong>an</strong>d thus<br />

to be risk-free 2 . Normally, sovereigns like the USA or Germ<strong>an</strong>y are considered to be<br />

non-defaultable or (default) risk-free.<br />

(c) The price of a zero-coupon bond c<strong>an</strong> also be calculated with discrete or linear interest-<br />

rates. This, however, leads to the same price. 3<br />

2<br />

To be precise, if we use the term risk-free in connection with interest-rates, we think of non-defaultable<br />

or default risk-free, i.e. not bearing credit risk.<br />

3<br />

The interest-rates are slightly different using discrete or linear rates, <strong>as</strong> well <strong>as</strong> the way to discount.<br />

For arbitrage re<strong>as</strong>ons, these effects c<strong>an</strong>cel out each other.<br />

68


Proposition 5.5 (Zero Rate)<br />

CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

Given the price of a zero-coupon bond P (t, T ), we c<strong>an</strong> e<strong>as</strong>ily calculate the zero rate by solv-<br />

ing for R(t, T )<br />

R(t, T ) = −<br />

ln (P (t, T ))<br />

. (5.2)<br />

T − t<br />

It is evident that modelling <strong>an</strong> interest-rate market is not e<strong>as</strong>y, <strong>as</strong> there are numerous<br />

different interest-rates, due to numerous different terms. One way to avoid the modelling<br />

of all interest rates is to model just one interest-rate which is able to describe the complete<br />

interest-rate curve – the so-called short-rate.<br />

Definition 5.6 (Short-Rate)<br />

The short-rate r(t) at time t is the interest-rate for <strong>an</strong> infinitesimal small time to matu-<br />

rity. Formally, we define<br />

ln P (t, t + ∆t)<br />

r(t) := R(t, t) := − lim<br />

= −<br />

∆t→0 ∆t<br />

∂<br />

∂T ln P (t, T )|T =t, (5.3)<br />

<strong>as</strong>suming that all derivatives <strong>an</strong>d limits exist.<br />

On this b<strong>as</strong>is, we c<strong>an</strong> now introduce the model of Zagst.<br />

5.2 Model of Zagst for Economic Scenario Generation<br />

In recent years, m<strong>an</strong>y models have been developed to describe stock <strong>an</strong>d interest-rate<br />

markets. The most famous model for describing stock markets is the model of Black <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Scholes, that uses a geometric Browni<strong>an</strong> motion to model the movement of stocks. In the<br />

field of interest-rate markets short-rate models are very popular. 4 Given the short-rate,<br />

the complete term structure of interest-rates c<strong>an</strong> be derived. This is explained later in<br />

this section for the Zagst model.<br />

Often, models for stocks <strong>an</strong>d interest-rates ch<strong>an</strong>ges are one-factor models, such <strong>as</strong> the<br />

V<strong>as</strong>icek model 5 . They only take into account their own absolute level, while neglecting<br />

the influence of, for example, macroeconomic factors like economic growth <strong>an</strong>d inflation.<br />

The model of Zagst is built up in a c<strong>as</strong>cade form taking into account both micro- <strong>an</strong>d<br />

macroeconomic factors. 6 Figure 5.1 shows the structure of this model.<br />

C<strong>as</strong>cade 1 represents economic factors like economic growth (for example represented<br />

by the growth of the Gross Domestic Product (GDP)) <strong>an</strong>d inflation rate (for example<br />

represented by the growth of the Consumer Price Index (CPI)). This c<strong>as</strong>cade provides<br />

input factors for c<strong>as</strong>cade 2 representing the yield curve with the tre<strong>as</strong>ury yield curve <strong>an</strong>d<br />

credit spreads. The input factors for c<strong>as</strong>cade 3 (equity <strong>an</strong>d property returns) are factors<br />

of both c<strong>as</strong>cade 1 <strong>an</strong>d c<strong>as</strong>cade 2. In c<strong>as</strong>cade 4, sector returns are modelled with input<br />

factors of c<strong>as</strong>cade 3. The latter is out of scope of this thesis. The parameter estimation<br />

h<strong>as</strong> to be done in the order of the c<strong>as</strong>cades beginning with c<strong>as</strong>cade 1.<br />

4 We defined the short-rate in Section 5.1.<br />

5 For a description of the V<strong>as</strong>icek model we refer for example to [Zag02], p. 126.<br />

6 The model of Zagst is <strong>an</strong> extension of the extended model of Schmid <strong>an</strong>d Zagst (see [SZAI06]), providing<br />

<strong>an</strong> integrated modelling of stock <strong>an</strong>d bond markets, see [ZMH06] or [Mey05].<br />

69


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

Figure 5.1: Model of Zagst<br />

The c<strong>as</strong>cade form enables <strong>an</strong> integrated modelling of stock, interest-rate <strong>an</strong>d credit<br />

markets, allowing for a high model complexity while ensuring <strong>an</strong> e<strong>as</strong>y interpretability of<br />

the model.<br />

The processes in the c<strong>as</strong>cades are modeled with stoch<strong>as</strong>tic differential equations (SDE)<br />

which are described in the following. 7 Within the thesis, we use the GDP <strong>as</strong> single eco-<br />

nomic factor, driving the yield curve. The inflation rate, however, is used <strong>as</strong> additional<br />

economic factor to derive equity returns. Then, the resulting SDEs for c<strong>as</strong>cade 1 <strong>an</strong>d 2<br />

c<strong>an</strong> be found in [SZAI06].<br />

Note that all SDEs in the model of Zagst for c<strong>as</strong>cade 1 <strong>an</strong>d 2 have the me<strong>an</strong> reversion<br />

property, i.e. the modelled processes tend towards their long-term me<strong>an</strong>. If, for example<br />

in terms of the short-rate, its value is lower th<strong>an</strong> the me<strong>an</strong> reverting level, the short-rate<br />

is pulled up. If, on the other h<strong>an</strong>d, the short-rate is higher th<strong>an</strong> its me<strong>an</strong> reverting level,<br />

it is pulled down. This property c<strong>an</strong> actually be observed in the market. 8<br />

C<strong>as</strong>cade 1 At first, we introduce the SDEs for c<strong>as</strong>cade 1. The dynamics of the GDP<br />

growth rate ω is described by a V<strong>as</strong>icek model. It is given by<br />

dω(t) = (θω − aωω(t)) dt + σωdWω(t), (5.4)<br />

where aω, σω are positive const<strong>an</strong>ts, θω is a non-negative const<strong>an</strong>t <strong>an</strong>d dWω(t) is a st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

Browni<strong>an</strong> motion 9 .<br />

The me<strong>an</strong> reverting level (MRL) for the GDP growth rate is given by θω<br />

, where aω<br />

aω<br />

determines the reversion rate.<br />

7 SDEs are a major tool to describe the behavior of fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>sets <strong>an</strong>d derivatives. For a definition, see<br />

Section A.2. For more theoretical background regarding SDEs, we refer for example to [BK04] or [Zag02].<br />

8 See [Zag02], p. 133.<br />

9 Browni<strong>an</strong> motion is defined in A.7.<br />

70


with<br />

CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

The dynamics of the short inflation i is given by<br />

di(t) = (θi − aii(t)) dt + σidWiω(t), (5.5)<br />

Wiω =<br />

�<br />

1 − ρ 2 iω Wi + ρiωWω.<br />

Here ai, σi are positive const<strong>an</strong>ts, θi is a non-negative const<strong>an</strong>t, ρiω denotes the linear<br />

correlation coefficient 10 between the processes i <strong>an</strong>d ω, with −1 ≤ ρiω ≤ 1, dWi(t) <strong>an</strong>d<br />

dWω(t) are a st<strong>an</strong>dard Browni<strong>an</strong> motions.<br />

The me<strong>an</strong> reverting level (MRL) for the short inflation is given by θi<br />

ai .<br />

C<strong>as</strong>cade 2 The dynamics of the non-defaultable nominal short-rate r is described by a<br />

two-factor Hull-White model, which is given by<br />

dr(t) = (θr(t) + brω(t) − arr(t)) dt + σrdWr(t), (5.11)<br />

where ar, br, σr are positive const<strong>an</strong>ts, θr(t) 11 is a continuous, deterministic function <strong>an</strong>d<br />

dWr(t) is a st<strong>an</strong>dard Browni<strong>an</strong> motion.<br />

The me<strong>an</strong> reverting level for the non-defaultable nominal short-rate is given by<br />

MRLr(t) = θr(t)+brω(t)<br />

. ar<br />

As one c<strong>an</strong> see, the growth rate of the GDP at time t h<strong>as</strong> a positive influence on the<br />

me<strong>an</strong> reverting level of the short-rate, i.e. a higher GDP leads to a higher long-term me<strong>an</strong><br />

of the short rate.<br />

Now, we define the second process within c<strong>as</strong>cade 2 – the short-rate credit spread. Its<br />

dynamics is described by a three-factor model, where one driving factor is the so-called<br />

uncertainty index u. It c<strong>an</strong> be interpreted <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> aggregation of all available information<br />

10 Let X be a r<strong>an</strong>dom variable with density function f. Then, the me<strong>an</strong> E(X) of a r<strong>an</strong>dom variable X<br />

is defined by<br />

E(X) :=<br />

� +∞<br />

−∞<br />

The vari<strong>an</strong>ce V(X) of a r<strong>an</strong>dom variable X is defined by<br />

Then, its st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation is given by<br />

x · f(x)dx. (5.6)<br />

V(X) := E (X − E(X)) 2¡ . (5.7)<br />

σ(X) := � V(X). (5.8)<br />

Let X1, . . . , Xn be r<strong>an</strong>dom variables with E(X 2 ) < ∞, k = 1, . . . , n. For V(Xi) > 0 <strong>an</strong>d V(Xj) > 0 the<br />

Pearson correlation coefficient of Xi <strong>an</strong>d Xj is defined by<br />

ρ(Xi, Xj) = ρi,j :=<br />

Cov(Xi, Xj)<br />

, i, j = 1, . . . , n, (5.9)<br />

σ(Xi) · σ(Xj)<br />

with covari<strong>an</strong>ce of Xi <strong>an</strong>d Xj, Cov(Xi, Xj) given by<br />

�<br />

�<br />

Cov(Xi, Xj) := E (Xi − E(Xi)) · (Xj − E(Xj)) , i, j = 1, . . . , n. (5.10)<br />

11 An explicit expression of θr(t) <strong>an</strong>d its derivation is given for example in [Mey05], pp. 40. θr(t) is<br />

determined in such a way that the interest-rate curve at simulation start date fits the market curve. More<br />

information about θr(t) <strong>an</strong>d its connection to the interest-rate curve c<strong>an</strong> be found in 5.3.<br />

71


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

about the quality of the firm. The higher the value of the uncertainty process the lower<br />

the firm’s quality. 12<br />

The dynamics of the short-rate spread is described by<br />

du(t) = [θu − auu(t)] dt + σudWu(t), (5.12)<br />

ds(t) = [θs + bsuu(t) − bsωω(t) − <strong>as</strong>s(t)] dt + σsdWs(t), (5.13)<br />

where au, σu, bsu, bsω, <strong>as</strong>, σs are positive const<strong>an</strong>ts, θu, θs are non-negative const<strong>an</strong>ts <strong>an</strong>d<br />

dWu(t), dWs(t) are st<strong>an</strong>dard Browni<strong>an</strong> motions.<br />

The me<strong>an</strong> reverting level for the short-rate spread is given by<br />

MRLs(t) = θs+bsuu(t)−bsωω(t)<br />

.<br />

<strong>as</strong><br />

The me<strong>an</strong> reverting level <strong>an</strong>d the drift of the short-rate spread s depend on two more<br />

factors besides s, namely ω <strong>an</strong>d u. This c<strong>an</strong> be interpreted <strong>as</strong> follows. If the GDP grows<br />

at a higher rate, spreads usually tighten <strong>as</strong> the probability of default of a firm gets smaller,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d vice versa. This negative correlation is expressed by a negative sign. u represents the<br />

firm specific risk <strong>an</strong>d h<strong>as</strong> a positive influence on credit spreads, i.e. a higher risk implies<br />

a higher credit spread. 13<br />

C<strong>as</strong>cade 3 Continuous stock returns RE(t) are also modelled with a SDE. The dynamics<br />

of RE(t) for the period [0, t] is expressed according to<br />

dRE(t) = [αE + bEωω(t) − (bER + bEi)i(t) + bERr(t)] dt + σEdWE(t), (5.14)<br />

where αE, bEω, bEi, bER, σE are positive const<strong>an</strong>ts <strong>an</strong>d dWE(t) is a st<strong>an</strong>dard Browni<strong>an</strong><br />

motion. 14<br />

The process for the stock returns does not have the me<strong>an</strong> reverting property. Regarding<br />

equation (5.14) it becomes obvious that both, the short-rate <strong>an</strong>d the GDP growth rate,<br />

have a positive influence on the stock returns.<br />

Processes under the Equivalent Martingale Me<strong>as</strong>ure So far, we saw the dynamics<br />

of the SDEs (given by the equations (5.4) – (5.13)) under the real me<strong>as</strong>ure Q. Though, <strong>as</strong><br />

we are interested in zero-coupon bond prices <strong>as</strong> well <strong>as</strong> interest-rates <strong>an</strong>d credit spreads<br />

for different terms, we need to know the parameters for the SDEs under the risk-neutral<br />

equivalent Martingale me<strong>as</strong>ure ˆ Q. 15<br />

As shown for example in [SZAI06], the ˆ Q-dynamics of ω, r, u <strong>an</strong>d s are given by<br />

dω(t) = (θω − âωω(t)) dt + σωd ˆ Wω(t), (5.15)<br />

dr(t) = (θr(t) + brω(t) − ârr(t)) dt + σrd ˆ Wr(t), (5.16)<br />

12<br />

See [SZAI06], p. 9.<br />

13<br />

According to [SZAI06], p. 13, this is in line with literature.<br />

14<br />

See [ZMH06].<br />

15<br />

For <strong>an</strong> introduction into risk neutral valuation, we refer for example to [BK04].<br />

72


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

du(t) = [θu − âuu(t)] dt + σud ˆ Wu(t), (5.17)<br />

ds(t) = [θs + bsuu(t) − bsωω(t) − âss(t)] dt + σsd ˆ Ws(t), (5.18)<br />

where âi = ai + λiσ 2 i , i = ω, r, u, s. λω, λr, λu, λs are obtained when ch<strong>an</strong>ging me<strong>as</strong>ure<br />

from Q to ˆ Q by applying Girs<strong>an</strong>ov’s Theorem 16 . 17<br />

Now, the foundation is built to determine zero-coupon bond prices in the Zagst model<br />

for both non-defaultable <strong>an</strong>d defaultable zero-coupon bonds, which in turn are the b<strong>as</strong>is<br />

for calculating the zero rates.<br />

Theorem 5.7 (Price of a non-defaultable zero-coupon bond)<br />

The time t price of a non-defaultable zero-coupon bond with maturity T is given by<br />

with<br />

<strong>an</strong>d<br />

Proof:<br />

A(t, T ) =<br />

P (t, T ) = P (t, T, r(t), ω(t)) = e A(t,T )−B(t,T )r(t)−D(t,T )ω(t) ,<br />

D(t, T ) = br<br />

� T<br />

t<br />

âr<br />

B(t, T ) = 1<br />

âr<br />

�<br />

1 − e−âω(T −t)<br />

âω<br />

�<br />

−âr(T<br />

1 − e<br />

−t)�<br />

,<br />

+ e−âω(T −t) − e<br />

âω − âr<br />

−âr(T −t)<br />

�<br />

1<br />

2 (σ2 rB(l, T ) 2 + σ 2 ωD(l, T ) 2 �<br />

) − θr(l)B(l, T ) − θωD(l, T ) dl.<br />

See [SZAI06]. �<br />

From zero-coupon bond prices the implicit rate of return c<strong>an</strong> e<strong>as</strong>ily be calculated<br />

according to the following theorem.<br />

Theorem 5.8 (Zero Rate)<br />

The zero rate (or spot rate) of a non-defaultable zero-coupon bond at time t with maturity<br />

T is given by<br />

R(t, T ) = −1<br />

[A(t, T ) − B(t, T )r(t) − D(t, T )ω(t)] (5.19)<br />

T − t<br />

with A(t, T ), B(t, T ), D(t, T ) <strong>as</strong> in Theorem 5.7.<br />

Proof:<br />

The zero rate R(t, T ) c<strong>an</strong> be calculated plugging P (t, T ) into equation (5.2). �<br />

Theorem 5.9 (Price of a defaultable zero-coupon bond)<br />

The price of a defaultable zero-coupon bond at time t < min(τ, T ), with maturitiy T <strong>an</strong>d<br />

default time τ, is given by<br />

P d (t, T ) = P (t, T, r(t), ω(t), u(t), s(t)) = e Ad (t,T )−B(t,T )r(t)−D d (t,T )ω(t)−E d (t,T )u(t)−F d (t,T )s(t) ,<br />

16 Girs<strong>an</strong>ov Theorem is given in A.18.<br />

17 See [SZAI06] pp. 12-13.<br />

�<br />

73


with<br />

<strong>an</strong>d<br />

Proof:<br />

A d (t, T ) =<br />

D d (t, T ) = br<br />

− bsω<br />

âs<br />

CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

âr<br />

E d (t, T ) = bsu<br />

� T<br />

t<br />

� T<br />

+<br />

B(t, T ) = 1<br />

âr<br />

�<br />

1 − e−âω(T −t)<br />

âω<br />

�<br />

1 − e−âω(T −t)<br />

âs<br />

âω<br />

�<br />

1 − e−âu(T −t)<br />

âu<br />

F d (t, T ) = 1<br />

âs<br />

�<br />

−âr(T<br />

1 − e<br />

−t)�<br />

,<br />

+ e−âω(T −t) − e<br />

+ e−âω(T −t) − e<br />

âω − âs<br />

âω − âr<br />

−âs(T −t)<br />

+ e−âu(T −t) − e<br />

âu − âs<br />

�<br />

−âs(T<br />

1 − e<br />

−t)�<br />

,<br />

−âr(T −t)<br />

�<br />

−âs(T −t)<br />

�<br />

1<br />

2 (σ2 rB(l, T ) 2 + σ 2 ωD d (l, T ) 2 + σ 2 uE d (l, T ) 2 + σ 2 sF d (l, T ) 2 �<br />

) dl<br />

�<br />

−θr(l)B(l, T ) − θωD d (l, T ) − θuE d (l, T ) − θsF d �<br />

(l, T ) dl.<br />

t<br />

See [SZAI06]. �<br />

Theorem 5.10 (Defaultable Zero Rate <strong>an</strong>d <strong>Credit</strong> Spread)<br />

The zero rate (or spot rate) of a defaultable zero-coupon bond at time t < min(τ, T ), with<br />

maturity T <strong>an</strong>d default time τ, is given by<br />

R d (t, T ) = − 1<br />

�<br />

A<br />

T − t<br />

d (t, T ) − B(t, T )r(t) − D d (t, T )ω(t)<br />

−E d (t, T )u(t) − F d �<br />

(t, T )s(t) .<br />

Furthermore, the credit spread is given by<br />

S(t, T ) = −1<br />

�<br />

A<br />

T − t<br />

d (t, T ) − A(t, T ) − (D d (t, T ) − D(t, T ))ω(t)<br />

−E d (t, T )u(t) − F d �<br />

(t, T )s(t) ,<br />

with A(t, T ), B(t, T ), D(t, T ), A d (t, T ), D d (t, T ), E d (t, T ), F d (t, T ) <strong>as</strong> in Theorem 5.7 <strong>an</strong>d<br />

5.9, respectively.<br />

Proof:<br />

For calculating the zero rate R d (t, T ) see proof of Theorem 5.8.<br />

The credit spread c<strong>an</strong> be e<strong>as</strong>ily calculated by S(t, T ) = R d (t, T ) − R(t, T ). �<br />

The model of Zagst is used for economic scenario generation for the following <strong>an</strong>alyses.<br />

<strong>risklab</strong> germ<strong>an</strong>y GmbH implemented <strong>an</strong> economic scenario generator (ESG), b<strong>as</strong>ed on the<br />

�<br />

�<br />

74


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

model described above. Before we c<strong>an</strong> start the simulations, we need to calibrate the ESG<br />

to real data. This is described in Section 7.1.1. In the following section, we show how to<br />

fit the interest-rate curve at simulation start date to market data.<br />

5.3 Fitting of the Interest-Rate Curve<br />

We already saw the function θr(t) in the dynamics of the short-rate process (see equation<br />

(5.11)). θr(t) h<strong>as</strong> to be fitted in such a way that at simulation start date, the current<br />

interest-rate curve is described <strong>as</strong> good <strong>as</strong> possible. We need to know the complete interest-<br />

rate curve at that date. From Bloomberg, for example, we get zero rates for different terms<br />

(3 months, 6 months, 1 year, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 15, 20 <strong>an</strong>d 30 years). A very popular<br />

method to obtain the complete interest-rate curve from single data points goes back to<br />

Nelson <strong>an</strong>d Siegel 18 . They describe the curve by<br />

T −t<br />

1 − exp(− β3<br />

R(t, T ) = β0 + (β1 + β2) · )<br />

T − t<br />

− β2 · exp(− ), (5.20)<br />

T −t<br />

β3<br />

β3<br />

using only four parameters. The limits c<strong>an</strong> be calculated <strong>as</strong><br />

<strong>an</strong>d<br />

lim<br />

(T −t)→0 R(t, T ) = β0 + β1, (5.21)<br />

lim<br />

(T −t)→∞ R(t, T ) = β0. (5.22)<br />

From equation (5.22) we see that β0 describes the interest-rate curve for long terms,<br />

while short-term interest-rates are determined by the sum of β0 <strong>an</strong>d β1 (see equation<br />

(5.21)). β2 <strong>an</strong>d β3 are shape factors, on the contrary. All common interest-rate structures<br />

(normal, flat, inverse, convex, concave) c<strong>an</strong> be produced with a curve described by equation<br />

(5.20), which is shown in Figure 5.2. 19 The figure shows different outcomes of interest-rate<br />

curves with parameters β0 = 5%, β1 = −1%, β2 ∈ {−6%, −3%, 0%, 3%, 6%, 9%, 12%} <strong>an</strong>d<br />

β3 = 100%.<br />

With the ESG, we simulate the government interest-rate curve, the credit spread curve<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the curve of the quoted CDS indices which are the b<strong>as</strong>is for pricing various fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

instruments. We price these instruments taking into account correlated defaults of the<br />

reference entities. One way how to obtain correlated default times, is described in the<br />

next section.<br />

5.4 Simulation of Correlated Default Times<br />

For the pricing of different fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, particularly corporate-related instru-<br />

ments, it is necessary to also consider defaults. We use a one-factor copula approach to<br />

generate correlated default times. On the one h<strong>an</strong>d, we use the Gaussi<strong>an</strong> copula, which<br />

is quite popular in practice due to <strong>an</strong> e<strong>as</strong>y implementation <strong>an</strong>d the properties of a st<strong>an</strong>-<br />

dard normal distribution, such <strong>as</strong> the stability under convolution. On the other h<strong>an</strong>d,<br />

18 For details we refer to [NS87].<br />

19 Inspired by [NS87].<br />

75


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

Figure 5.2: Nelson-Siegel interest-rate curves<br />

we use the normal inverse Gaussi<strong>an</strong> (NIG) copula, which is able to overcome the mod-<br />

elling deficiencies of the Gaussi<strong>an</strong> copula while remaining the property of stability under<br />

convolution. To determine the correlated default times, it is necessary to determine a<br />

distribution function for the default time τ. For this re<strong>as</strong>on, we use a migration matrices<br />

approach, which is described in the following section.<br />

5.4.1 Migration Matrices Approach<br />

In this subsection, we primarily follow [Blu03]. 20<br />

It is common sense <strong>an</strong>d also confirmed for example by St<strong>an</strong>dard & Poor’s that there is<br />

a clear correlation between credit quality <strong>an</strong>d default remotedness: the higher the issuer’s<br />

rating, the lower its probability of default, <strong>an</strong>d vice versa. 21<br />

We <strong>as</strong>sume a set of ratings 22 R ∈ {AAA, AA, A, BBB, BB, B, CCC/C}, where AAA<br />

denotes the best credit quality, CCC/C denotes the worst non-defaulted credit quality<br />

<strong>an</strong>d R D ∈ {AAA, AA, A, BBB, BB, B, CCC/C, D}, where D denotes the state of default.<br />

Finding generalisations of the following results for finer rating scales is straightforward.<br />

Each rating cl<strong>as</strong>s c<strong>an</strong> be mapped to a unique probability of default. Table 5.1 shows<br />

the US average one year probability of default for each rating cl<strong>as</strong>s. 23<br />

The aim of this section is to find a distribution function for the default time τ for <strong>an</strong>y<br />

given rating R. On our way, we need to calibrate a credit curve for each element of R.<br />

20 See [Blu03], pp. 12.<br />

21 See [Sta06], p. 16.<br />

22 For more information regarding ratings we refer to the corresponding paragraph in Section 2.2.2 <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Appendix B.<br />

23 The underlying data is taken from [Sta06] p. 15.<br />

76


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

Rating One-Year PD<br />

AAA 0.00%<br />

AA 0.01%<br />

A 0.04%<br />

BBB 0.30%<br />

BB 1.20%<br />

B 6.05%<br />

CCC/C 31.49%<br />

Table 5.1: US average one-year probability of default, 1981 to 2005<br />

Definition 5.11 (<strong>Credit</strong> Curve)<br />

A credit curve for a rating R is a mapping<br />

t ↦→ Q (R) (t) = P[R(t) = D | R(0)] (t ≥ 0; R(0) ∈ {AAA, AA, ..., CCC/C}),<br />

where D denotes the default state <strong>an</strong>d R(t) the rating at time t.<br />

Thus, Q (R) (t) is the probability that <strong>an</strong> issuer with a current rating R(0) defaults<br />

within the next t years. Therefore, Table 5.1 displays the credit curve with Q (R) (1).<br />

There are several ways to calibrate a credit curve. One way is to use a Markov chain 24<br />

approach, b<strong>as</strong>ed on one-year migration matrices published by rating agencies 25 .<br />

A migration or tr<strong>an</strong>sition matrix is a quadratic matrix describing the probabilities of<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ging from one state to <strong>an</strong>other.<br />

Table 5.2 shows the tr<strong>an</strong>sition matrix containing US average one-year tr<strong>an</strong>sition rates<br />

from 1981 to 2005, where issuers who withdrew their rating were removed <strong>an</strong>d the row<br />

sums were normalised so that they sum up to one. 26<br />

AAA AA A BBB BB B CCC/C D<br />

AAA 92.24% 7.07% 0.55% 0.04% 0.09% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%<br />

AA 0.62% 90.71% 7.69% 0.70% 0.07% 0.16% 0.03% 0.01%<br />

A 0.06% 1.95% 91.22% 5.97% 0.52% 0.19% 0.04% 0.05%<br />

BBB 0.02% 0.18% 4.01% 89.68% 4.85% 0.82% 0.14% 0.30%<br />

BB 0.05% 0.07% 0.34% 6.03% 82.68% 8.80% 0.83% 1.20%<br />

B 0.00% 0.07% 0.23% 0.34% 5.83% 82.63% 4.86% 6.05%<br />

CCC/C 0.00% 0.00% 0.42% 0.62% 1.56% 10.81% 55.10% 31.49%<br />

D 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 100.00%<br />

Table 5.2: US average one-year tr<strong>an</strong>sition rates, 1981 to 2005<br />

This matrix h<strong>as</strong> to be read <strong>as</strong> follows. The probability for <strong>an</strong> issuer who is AAA-rated<br />

in t to become AA-rated in t + 1 is 7.07% or to become A-rated in t + 1 is 0.55%.<br />

The migration matrix M = (mij)i,j=1,...,8 from Table 5.2 is needed for the following<br />

theorem.<br />

24 For some background regarding Markov chains we refer for example to [Nor98].<br />

25 See for example [Sta06]. They provide tables for tr<strong>an</strong>sition rates by region for a certain year (p.14),<br />

or global average one-year tr<strong>an</strong>sitions rates for a certain period (pp. 15-16).<br />

26 The average one-year tr<strong>an</strong>sition matrix for the Europe<strong>an</strong> Union from 1981 to 2005 is given in Appendix<br />

D.<br />

77


Theorem 5.12 (Log-Exp<strong>an</strong>sion)<br />

CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

Let I be the identity matrix <strong>an</strong>d M = (mij)i,j=1,...,n a migration matrix which is strictly<br />

diagonal domin<strong>an</strong>t, i.e. mii > 1<br />

2<br />

Õn =<br />

for every i. Then, the log-exp<strong>an</strong>sion<br />

n�<br />

k+1 (M − I)k<br />

(−1)<br />

k<br />

k=1<br />

converges to a matrix Õ = (oij)i,j=1,...,n satisfying<br />

1. � n<br />

j=1 õij = 0 ∀i = 1, ..., n,<br />

2. exp( Õ) = M.27<br />

The convergence Õn → Õ is geometrically f<strong>as</strong>t.<br />

Proof:<br />

(n ∈ N)<br />

See [Blu03]. �<br />

Remark 5.13<br />

The generator of a time-continuous Markov chain is given by a matrix O, O = (oij)1≤i,j≤n,<br />

satisfying the following properties:<br />

1. � n<br />

j=1 oij = 0 ∀i = 1, ..., n,<br />

2. −∞ < oii ≤ 0 ∀i = 1, ..., n,<br />

3. oij ≥ 0 ∀i = 1, ..., n with i �= j.<br />

Theorem 5.14 is a st<strong>an</strong>dard result from Markov chain theory.<br />

Theorem 5.14<br />

The following properties are equivalent for a matrix O ∈ R n×n .<br />

(a) O satisfies properties 1 to 3 in Remark 5.13.<br />

(b) exp(tO) is a stoch<strong>as</strong>tic matrix ∀ t ≥ 0.<br />

Proof:<br />

See [Nor98], Theorem 2.1.2. �<br />

Using Theorem 5.12, Remark 5.13 <strong>an</strong>d Theorem 5.14 we c<strong>an</strong> construct credit curves<br />

for every time t <strong>an</strong>d every rating cl<strong>as</strong>s R. At first, we calculate the log-exp<strong>an</strong>sion Õ =<br />

(õij)i,j=1,...,8 of the adjusted one-year migration matrix M = (mij)i,j=1,...,n with Theorem<br />

5.12. The resulting matrix Õ is displayed in Table 5.3.<br />

In order to be a generator matrix,<br />

Õ h<strong>as</strong> to satisfy the properties enumerated in<br />

Remark 5.13. Property 1 is satisfied because it is guar<strong>an</strong>teed by Theorem 5.12. Obviously,<br />

27 The matrix exponential function is defined <strong>an</strong>alogously to the ordinary exponential function:<br />

Let X be a n × n matrix, the exponential of X, denoted by exp(X), is defined <strong>as</strong><br />

exp(X) = �∞ X<br />

k=0<br />

k<br />

k! .<br />

78


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

AAA AA A BBB BB B CCC/C D<br />

AAA -8.10% 7.73% 0.28% 0.01% 0.10% -0.01% 0.00% 0.00%<br />

AA 0.68% -9.86% 8.45% 0.49% 0.04% 0.17% 0.03% 0.00%<br />

A 0.06% 2.13% -9.43% 6.59% 0.41% 0.16% 0.04% 0.03%<br />

BBB 0.02% 0.15% 4.43% -11.24% 5.61% 0.65% 0.14% 0.24%<br />

BB 0.06% 0.06% 0.22% 7.00% -19.61% 10.60% 0.82% 0.84%<br />

B 0.00% 0.07% 0.23% 0.12% 7.02% -19.96% 7.16% 5.37%<br />

CCC/C 0.00% -0.01% 0.54% 0.78% 1.68% 15.88% -60.27% 41.41%<br />

D 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%<br />

Table 5.3: Log-exp<strong>an</strong>sion of M<br />

property 2 is also satisfied. But property 3 is hurt twice by õAAA,B <strong>an</strong>d by õ CCC/C,AA.<br />

Bluhm suggests to set these values to zero <strong>an</strong>d in return, to decre<strong>as</strong>e the diagonal elements<br />

of the corresponding rows. The resulting matrix is the generator matrix O = (oij)i,j=1,...,8.<br />

Bluhm justifies this m<strong>an</strong>ipulation since the implied error, calculated <strong>as</strong> euclidi<strong>an</strong> dist<strong>an</strong>ce 28<br />

of M <strong>an</strong>d exp(O)<br />

is negligible.<br />

||M − exp(O)||2<br />

Now, we c<strong>an</strong> calculate the credit curve 29 for every t ≥ 0 by<br />

Q (R) (t) = (exp(tO)) i(R),8,<br />

where i(R) denotes the tr<strong>an</strong>sition matrix row corresponding to the given rating R. Figure<br />

5.3 shows the credit curve calculated on a quarterly b<strong>as</strong>is for 400 years.<br />

It becomes obvious that the probability for a default within the next t years is the higher<br />

the worse the credit quality is. Furthermore, it c<strong>an</strong> be observed that the sub-investment-<br />

grade ratings slow down their growth, because – conditional on having survived for some<br />

time – the probability for further survival improves.<br />

If we <strong>as</strong>sume the credit curves Q (R) (t) to be correct <strong>an</strong>d really to give us the cumulative<br />

default probabilities for <strong>an</strong>y rating R over <strong>an</strong>y time interval [0, t], there is only one way to<br />

define the distribution of default time τ for <strong>an</strong> R-rated issuer, also stated in Lemma 5.15.<br />

Lemma 5.15<br />

Given a credit curve (Q (R) (t))t≥0 for a rating R, there exists a unique default times dis-<br />

tribution for R-rated obligors.<br />

Proof:<br />

Let us define a r<strong>an</strong>dom variable τ (R) with τ (R) ∈ [0, ∞). Then the distribution function<br />

for τ (R) is given by<br />

�<br />

Fτ (R)(t) = P τ (R) �<br />

≤ t = Q (R) (t). (5.23)<br />

28 The euclidi<strong>an</strong> dist<strong>an</strong>ce is the length of a vector x ∈ R n <strong>an</strong>d is defined <strong>as</strong> follows:<br />

29 See Definition 5.11.<br />

||x||2 := �� n<br />

i=1 x2 i .<br />

79


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

Figure 5.3: <strong>Credit</strong> curve (Q (R) (t))0≤t≤400<br />

Equation (5.23) is used when we generate correlated default times with one-factor<br />

copula models <strong>as</strong> described in Section 5.4.2.<br />

5.4.2 One-Factor Copula<br />

As described in detail in Chapter 3, there are single-name credit derivatives, such <strong>as</strong> credit<br />

default swaps <strong>an</strong>d total return swaps b<strong>as</strong>ed upon a single underlying credit risk, <strong>an</strong>d multi-<br />

name credit derivatives that are <strong>as</strong>sociated with a portfolio of credit risks. Central to the<br />

pricing of multi-name credit derivatives is the problem of default correlation.<br />

In reality, during a recession more firms default th<strong>an</strong> during a booming period. This<br />

implies that each firm is subject to the same set of macroeconomic environment, <strong>an</strong>d that<br />

there exists a dependence among the firms.<br />

The one-factor copula approach for modelling correlated default times h<strong>as</strong> become very<br />

popular. It is <strong>as</strong>sumed that defaults of different titles in the portfolio are independent,<br />

conditional on a common market factor. We begin with <strong>an</strong> introduction of the one-factor<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> copula.<br />

One-Factor Gaussi<strong>an</strong> Copula<br />

In this section we follow primarily [HW04] <strong>an</strong>d [KSW05]. After having defined the normal<br />

distribution 30 , we define the one-factor Gaussi<strong>an</strong> copula.<br />

Definition 5.16 (Normal Distribution)<br />

A r<strong>an</strong>dom variable X follows a normal distribution with me<strong>an</strong> µ <strong>an</strong>d vari<strong>an</strong>ce σ 2 , if its<br />

density function h<strong>as</strong> the form<br />

30 The terms ”normal distribution” <strong>an</strong>d ”Gaussi<strong>an</strong> distribution” c<strong>an</strong> be used synonymously.<br />

�<br />

80


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

fN (x) =<br />

�<br />

1<br />

(x − µ)2<br />

√ · exp −<br />

2πσ2 2σ2 �<br />

. (5.24)<br />

We denote the distribution function by FN (x) <strong>an</strong>d we write X ∼ N (µ, σ 2 ).<br />

Definition 5.17 (One-Factor Gaussi<strong>an</strong> Copula)<br />

Consider a portfolio of m credit instruments. The st<strong>an</strong>dardised <strong>as</strong>set return up to time t<br />

of the i th issuer in the portfolio, Ai(t), is <strong>as</strong>sumed to be of the form<br />

Ai(t) = aiM(t) +<br />

�<br />

1 − a2 i Xi(t), (5.25)<br />

where M(t) <strong>an</strong>d Xi(t), i = 1, ..., m are independent st<strong>an</strong>dard normally distributed r<strong>an</strong>dom<br />

variables.<br />

Let us <strong>as</strong>sume that default occurs when the <strong>as</strong>set return of obligor i falls below the threshold<br />

Ci(t), i.e. Ai(t) ≤ Ci(t). Using this copula model, the variable Ai(t) is then mapped to<br />

default time τi of the i th issuer with a percentile-to-percentile tr<strong>an</strong>sformation 31 , i.e.<br />

P[τi ≤ t] = P[Ai(t) ≤ Ci(t)]. (5.26)<br />

Note that – due to the stability of normal distributions under convolution – the <strong>as</strong>set<br />

return Ai(t) is also st<strong>an</strong>dard normally distributed.<br />

The factor M represents the systematic common market factor <strong>an</strong>d Xi represents<br />

firm-specific factors. Equation (5.25) defines a correlation structure between the r<strong>an</strong>dom<br />

variables Ai(t). The correlation between <strong>as</strong>set returns of the issuers i <strong>an</strong>d j is given by<br />

aiaj. Conditional on M the <strong>as</strong>set returns of different issuers are independent.<br />

Let the probability of the issuer i to default before time t be denoted by<br />

Qi(t) = P [τi ≤ t] , (5.27)<br />

where we use for Qi(t) the distribution function for default times derived in Section 5.4.1.<br />

Let n denote the number of scenarios <strong>an</strong>d m the number of correlated default times<br />

for one scenario. m is the number of reference entities that we w<strong>an</strong>t to consider, i.e. for<br />

every single-name instrument, such <strong>as</strong> a bond, we generate one default time, for a multi-<br />

name instrument, such <strong>as</strong> a CDS index, we generate for example 125 default times if the<br />

reference portfolio consists of 125 entities. We c<strong>an</strong> generate the correlated default times<br />

according to Algorithm 5.1.<br />

Algorithm 5.1 (Generation of correlated default times with a one-factor Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

copula model)<br />

1. Simulate M ∼ N (0, 1).<br />

2. Simulate Xi ∼ N (0, 1).<br />

�<br />

3. Compute Ai = aiM + 1 − a2 i Xi.<br />

31 In words: A percentile-to-percentile tr<strong>an</strong>sformation me<strong>an</strong>s that the k-percentile point in the probability<br />

distribution for Ai is tr<strong>an</strong>sformed to the k-percentile point in the probability distribution of τi.<br />

81


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

4. Determine the correlated default times for all i ∈ {1, ..., m} according to<br />

t = Q −1<br />

i [FN (Ai)].<br />

One technique that simplifies the <strong>an</strong>alysis of relatively homogeneous credit portfolios<br />

with m<strong>an</strong>y reference entities, such <strong>as</strong> CDS indices, is the so-called large homogeneous<br />

portfolio approximation method, introduced by V<strong>as</strong>icek ([V<strong>as</strong>87]). This approximation is<br />

<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>ymptotic version of the one-factor Gaussi<strong>an</strong> model of correlated defaults.<br />

Definition 5.18 (Large Homogeneous Portfolio (LHP))<br />

The large homogeneous portfolio is a portfolio consisting of a sufficiently large number of<br />

issuers having the same characteristics:<br />

• the same portfolio weight,<br />

• the same default probability Q(t),<br />

• the same recovery rate REC,<br />

• the same correlation to the market factor a.<br />

From this definition it becomes evident that the correlation between issuer i <strong>an</strong>d j<br />

reduces to a 2 , <strong>as</strong> the correlation between the addresses in the LHP approach is <strong>as</strong>sumed<br />

to be const<strong>an</strong>t <strong>an</strong>d equal, i.e. ai = a.<br />

One-Factor Normal Inverse Gaussi<strong>an</strong> Copula<br />

In this section, we first define <strong>an</strong>d describe the Normal Inverse Gaussi<strong>an</strong> (NIG) distribu-<br />

tion. Thereafter, we describe the one-factor NIG copula model, which w<strong>as</strong> introduced by<br />

Kalem<strong>an</strong>ova et. al 32 .<br />

Definition <strong>an</strong>d Properties of the Normal Inverse Gaussi<strong>an</strong> Distribution The<br />

NIG distribution is a mixture of normal <strong>an</strong>d inverse Gaussi<strong>an</strong> distributions. It is a four<br />

parameter distribution with very interesting properties: It c<strong>an</strong> produce fat tails <strong>an</strong>d skew-<br />

ness, it is stable under convolution (under certain conditions), <strong>an</strong>d the density function,<br />

the distribution function <strong>an</strong>d the inverse distribution function c<strong>an</strong> be computed sufficiently<br />

f<strong>as</strong>t. 33<br />

Definition 5.19 (Inverse Gaussi<strong>an</strong> Distribution)<br />

A non-negative r<strong>an</strong>dom variable X h<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> Inverse Gaussi<strong>an</strong> (IG) distribution with para-<br />

meters α > 0 <strong>an</strong>d β > 0 if its density function h<strong>as</strong> the form<br />

⎧<br />

⎪⎨<br />

fIG(x; α, β) =<br />

⎪⎩<br />

32 See [KSW05].<br />

33 See [KSW05] <strong>an</strong>d [Tem05].<br />

α<br />

√ x<br />

2πβ −3/2 �<br />

exp −<br />

�<br />

(α − βx)2<br />

2βx<br />

, if x > 0<br />

0 , if x ≤ 0.<br />

82


The corresponding distribution function is<br />

⎧<br />

⎪⎨<br />

FIG(x; α, β) =<br />

⎪⎩<br />

Then, we write X ∼ IG(α, β).<br />

CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

α<br />

√ 2πβ<br />

� x<br />

0<br />

z −3/2 �<br />

�<br />

(α − βz)2<br />

exp − dz , if x > 0<br />

2βz<br />

0 , if x ≤ 0.<br />

The four central statistics – me<strong>an</strong> 34 , vari<strong>an</strong>ce 35 , skewness 36 <strong>an</strong>d kurtosis 37 – are given<br />

by the following lemma.<br />

Lemma 5.20<br />

Me<strong>an</strong>, vari<strong>an</strong>ce, skewness <strong>an</strong>d kurtosis of <strong>an</strong> Inverse Gaussi<strong>an</strong> distributed r<strong>an</strong>dom variable<br />

X ∼ IG(α, β) are<br />

Proof:<br />

E(X) = α<br />

β<br />

V(X) = α<br />

β 2 S(X) = 3<br />

√ α<br />

K(X) = 3 + 15<br />

α .<br />

See [Tem05]. �<br />

Definition 5.21 (Normal Inverse Gaussi<strong>an</strong> distribution)<br />

A r<strong>an</strong>dom variable X follows a Normal Inverse Gaussi<strong>an</strong> (NIG) distribution with parame-<br />

ters α, β, µ <strong>an</strong>d δ if<br />

X | Y = y ∼ N (µ + βy, y)<br />

Y ∼ IG(δγ, γ 2 ) with γ := � α 2 − β 2 ,<br />

with parameters satisfying the following conditions: 0 ≤ |β| < α <strong>an</strong>d δ > 0. Then, we write<br />

X ∼ N IG(α, β, µ, δ) <strong>an</strong>d denote the density <strong>an</strong>d probability functions by fN IG(x; α, β, µ, δ)<br />

<strong>an</strong>d FN IG(x; α, β, µ, δ) correspondingly.<br />

34<br />

The me<strong>an</strong> is defined in equation (5.6) in footnote 10.<br />

35<br />

The vari<strong>an</strong>ce is defined in equation (5.7) in footnote 10.<br />

36<br />

We already defined the sample skewness in equation (4.8). Now we define the continuous version. Let<br />

E(X) <strong>an</strong>d σ 2 (X) denote the me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d the vari<strong>an</strong>ce of the r<strong>an</strong>dom variable X. For E(|X| 3 ) < ∞, the<br />

skewness S(X) of a r<strong>an</strong>dom variable X is defined <strong>as</strong><br />

�� � �<br />

3<br />

X − E(X)<br />

S(X) = E<br />

. (5.28)<br />

σ(X)<br />

37<br />

We already defined the sample excess kurtosis in equation (4.9). Now we define the continuous version<br />

of the kurtosis. Let E(X) <strong>an</strong>d σ 2 (X) denote the me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d the vari<strong>an</strong>ce of the r<strong>an</strong>dom variable X. For<br />

E(|X| 4 ) < ∞, the kurtosis K(X) of a r<strong>an</strong>dom variable X is defined <strong>as</strong><br />

�� � �<br />

4<br />

X − E(X)<br />

K(X) = E<br />

. (5.29)<br />

σ(X)<br />

83


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

The density of the NIG distribution is then<br />

fN IG(x; α, β, µ, δ) =<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the distribution function<br />

FN IG(x; α, β, µ, δ) =<br />

� x<br />

� ∞<br />

0<br />

−∞<br />

fN (x; µ + βy, y) · fIG(y; δγ, γ 2 )dy (5.30)<br />

� ∞<br />

0<br />

fN (z; µ + βy, y) · fIG(y; δγ, γ 2 )dydz (5.31)<br />

with fN (x; µ, σ 2 ) the density function of the Gaussi<strong>an</strong> distribution <strong>as</strong> given by Definition<br />

5.16.<br />

Figure 5.4 gives <strong>an</strong> impression of various forms of the density function with NIG<br />

distribution, depending on different parameter sets. Note that in every figure we only<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ge one of the parameters, while the others remain fixed. Additionally, we plot the<br />

density function of the st<strong>an</strong>dard normal distribution (solid red line) in every sub-figure to<br />

gain a deeper underst<strong>an</strong>ding of the forms of the NIG distributions.<br />

Figure 5.4: Densities of NIG distribution<br />

From Figure 5.4 we see that the NIG distribution c<strong>an</strong> produce fat tails <strong>an</strong>d skewness.<br />

The distribution is symmetric if β = 0. The central statistics of the distribution are given<br />

by the following lemma.<br />

84


Lemma 5.22<br />

CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

Me<strong>an</strong>, vari<strong>an</strong>ce, skewness <strong>an</strong>d kurtosis of a r<strong>an</strong>dom variable X ∼ N IG(α, β, µ, δ) are:<br />

Proof:<br />

E(X) = µ + δ β<br />

γ<br />

β<br />

S(X) = 3<br />

α · √ δγ<br />

V(X) = δ α2<br />

γ3 � � � �<br />

2<br />

β 1<br />

K(X) = 3 + 3 1 + 4<br />

α δγ .<br />

See [Tem05]. �<br />

The main properties of the NIG distribution are the scaling <strong>an</strong>d the convolution prop-<br />

erties which are given by the following lemma.<br />

Lemma 5.23<br />

(a) Let X be a NIG distributed r<strong>an</strong>dom variable (X ∼ N IG(α, β, µ, δ)) <strong>an</strong>d let c be a<br />

scalar, then cX is NIG distributed with parameters<br />

This is called scaling property.<br />

� �<br />

α β<br />

cX ∼ N IG , , cµ, cδ . (5.32)<br />

c c<br />

(b) Let X <strong>an</strong>d Y be independent r<strong>an</strong>dom variables with X ∼ N IG(α, β, µ1, δ1) <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Proof:<br />

Y ∼ N IG(α, β, µ2, δ2). Then, their sum is also NIG distributed with parameters<br />

X + Y ∼ N IG (α, β, µ1 + µ2, δ1 + δ2) . (5.33)<br />

See [KSW05]. �<br />

The convolution property (5.33) does not hold for arbitrary NIG r<strong>an</strong>dom variables X<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Y . X <strong>an</strong>d Y must rather have the same α <strong>an</strong>d β.<br />

One-Factor NIG Copula Model Now, we use the one-factor copula model of corre-<br />

lated defaults with a NIG distribution. For this re<strong>as</strong>on, we partly follow [KSW05] in this<br />

section.<br />

Definition 5.24 (One-factor NIG copula)<br />

Consider a homogeneous portfolio of m credit instruments. The st<strong>an</strong>dardised <strong>as</strong>set return<br />

up to time t of the i th issuer in the portfolio, Ai(t), is <strong>as</strong>sumed to be of the form<br />

with independent r<strong>an</strong>dom variables<br />

Ai(t) = aM(t) + � 1 − a 2 Xi(t), (5.34)<br />

�<br />

M(t) ∼ N IG<br />

α, β, − βγ2 γ3<br />

,<br />

α2 α2 �<br />

, (5.35)<br />

85


<strong>an</strong>d<br />

CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

�√ √ √<br />

1 − a2 1 − a2 1 − a2 Xi(t) ∼ N IG α, β, −<br />

a a<br />

a<br />

where γ = � α 2 − β 2 .<br />

βγ2 ,<br />

α2 √ 1 − a 2<br />

a<br />

γ3 α2 �<br />

, (5.36)<br />

Let us <strong>as</strong>sume that default occurs when the <strong>as</strong>set return of obligor i falls below the threshold<br />

Ci(t), i.e. Ai(t) ≤ Ci(t). Using this copula model, the variable Ai(t) is then mapped to<br />

default time τi of the i th issuer with a percentile-to-percentile tr<strong>an</strong>sformation, i.e.<br />

P[τi ≤ t] = P[Ai(t) ≤ C(t)]. (5.37)<br />

The distribution parameters for M(t) <strong>an</strong>d Xi(t) are chosen in such a way that the<br />

<strong>as</strong>set return Ai(t) also follows a NIG distribution with the parameters<br />

�<br />

α<br />

Ai ∼ N IG<br />

a<br />

β<br />

, , −1<br />

a a<br />

βγ2 1<br />

,<br />

α2 a<br />

γ3 α2 �<br />

. (5.38)<br />

This c<strong>an</strong> be e<strong>as</strong>ily verified by applying the scaling property (5.32) <strong>an</strong>d the stability under<br />

convolution (5.33). Furthermore, Ai(t) h<strong>as</strong> zero me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d unit vari<strong>an</strong>ce. �<br />

To simplify the notation, we denote the distribution function FN IG x; sα, sβ, −s βγ2<br />

α2 , s γ3<br />

α2 �<br />

by F N IG(s)(x). Then, the distribution function of the factor M is F N IG(1)(x), of the factor<br />

Xi, it is F √<br />

1−a2 N IG( ) a<br />

(x) <strong>an</strong>d of Ai, it is F 1<br />

N IG( a )(x).<br />

Let the probability of default before time t again be denoted by<br />

Q(t) = P [τi ≤ t] , (5.39)<br />

where we use for Q(t) the distribution function for default times derived in Section 5.4.1.<br />

Again, let n denote the number of scenarios <strong>an</strong>d m the number of correlated default<br />

times for one scenario. 38<br />

times.<br />

Analogous to Algorithm 5.1, we c<strong>an</strong> then generate a set of m × n correlated default<br />

Algorithm 5.2 (Generation of correlated default times with a one-factor NIG<br />

copula model)<br />

1. Simulate M, distributed according to equation (5.35).<br />

2. Simulate Xi, distributed according to equation (5.36).<br />

3. Compute Ai = aM + √ 1 − a 2 Xi.<br />

4. Determine the correlated default times for all i ∈ {1, ..., m} according to<br />

t = Q −1 [FN IG(Ai)].<br />

38 The procedure is the same <strong>as</strong> already explained in Section 5.4.2.<br />

86


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

We w<strong>an</strong>t to demonstrate the difference between correlated default times generated with<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d NIG copula. For this re<strong>as</strong>on, we simulate correlated default times for 5000<br />

pairs of equally rated firms with the migration matrices approach, described in Section<br />

5.4.1, with correlation between the reference entities of 0.1, 0.3, 0.5 <strong>an</strong>d 0.7. The results<br />

are displayed in Figure 5.5. The or<strong>an</strong>ge squares represent default times, generated with<br />

the NIG copula, the grey squares represent default times generated with the Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

copula. We are particularly interested in default times occurring in the next 10 years after<br />

generation, since this is a medium-term investment horizon.<br />

We make three main observations:<br />

• With a lower rating, pairwise default times incre<strong>as</strong>e signific<strong>an</strong>tly within the first 10<br />

years.<br />

• Pairwise default times incre<strong>as</strong>e signific<strong>an</strong>tly with a higher correlation between the<br />

reference entities within the first 10 years.<br />

• Pairwise defaults occur more frequently within a 10-year time horizon, if the default<br />

times are simulated with one-factor NIG copula.<br />

Furthermore, we show the outcome of step 3 in the Algorithms 5.1 <strong>an</strong>d 5.2 for rating<br />

cl<strong>as</strong>s AA with correlation of 0.3, from the simulation above. The result is shown in Figure<br />

5.6.<br />

Here, it becomes obvious that the one-factor NIG copula produces considerably more<br />

negative <strong>as</strong>set returns of several issuers th<strong>an</strong> the one-factor Gauss copula. This implies a<br />

higher potential of joint defaults, which in turn h<strong>as</strong> implications on the pricing of fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

instruments, particularly CDO tr<strong>an</strong>ches. 39<br />

39 See [KSW05] for the fit of CDO tr<strong>an</strong>ches with one-factor Gauss <strong>an</strong>d one-factor NIG copula.<br />

87


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

Figure 5.5: Correlated default times with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d NIG one-factor copula model<br />

88


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

Figure 5.6: One-factor Gaussi<strong>an</strong> copula vs. one-factor NIG copula<br />

89


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

5.5 Pricing of Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Instruments<br />

Before pricing, we simulate 1000 scenarios with the ESG on a quarterly b<strong>as</strong>is for 5 years.<br />

Therefore, we have 21 timesteps for each scenario in the end, <strong>as</strong> the first one is the start<br />

date 30 th of September, 2006. As output 40 from the simulation we obtain for each scenario<br />

<strong>an</strong>d for every timestep<br />

• a zero curve for government bonds, R(t, T ), which is supposed to be non-defaultable,<br />

• a credit spread curve for the rating cl<strong>as</strong>ses R ∈ {AA, A, BBB}, SR(t, T ) (i. e. credit<br />

spreads for different terms),<br />

• a curve for the quoted spread of the CDS index 41 , SCDS−index(t, T ),<br />

• return of <strong>an</strong> equity index.<br />

Then, we have to generate correlated default times for each simulated scenario. For<br />

this re<strong>as</strong>on, we apply a migration matrices approach 42 , which generates correlated default<br />

times with both, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d NIG copula, <strong>as</strong> described by the Algorithms 5.1 <strong>an</strong>d 5.2,<br />

respectively.<br />

The ESG provides us with interest-rate curves, credit spread curves <strong>an</strong>d the curve<br />

for the CDS index with certain terms. For pricing issues, however, we will also need<br />

arbitrary maturities not necessarily coinciding with simulated maturities. 43 Besides, we<br />

will occ<strong>as</strong>ionally need the interest-rate curve at <strong>an</strong> arbitrary time t, which is not simulated.<br />

For this re<strong>as</strong>on, we conduct a linear interpolation of the curves, if necessary.<br />

We price the instruments at every simulated timestep tk, k ∈ {0, ..., m} 44 , with<br />

t0 < t1 < ... < tm = T sim ,<br />

where T sim denotes the end date of the simulation. As we conduct quarterly simulations,<br />

the stepsize of the simulated timesteps, denoted by ∆tk, is in our c<strong>as</strong>e ∆tk = tk − tk−1 =<br />

0.25.<br />

Remark 5.25<br />

The pricing for all considered instruments is done under the conditions listed below.<br />

(a) It is always <strong>as</strong>sumed that the c<strong>as</strong>h flows occurring before maturity T are reinvested<br />

in the considered instrument.<br />

(b) The c<strong>as</strong>h flows at maturity T or at default time τ are invested in a risk-free c<strong>as</strong>h<br />

account with the default risk-free 3 month government rate, if T or τ occur before<br />

T sim , i.e. if min(τ, T ) < T sim .<br />

(c) The pricing is always done for <strong>an</strong> initial investment of one unit.<br />

40<br />

All output values are determined according to equations given in Section 5.2.<br />

41<br />

The dynamics for quoted CDS spreads is calculated using Itô’s Lemma. The calculation c<strong>an</strong> be found<br />

in Appendix C.<br />

42<br />

See Section 5.4.1.<br />

43<br />

For example, think of the pricing day half a year after simulation start date. A zero-coupon bond with<br />

<strong>an</strong> original term of 5 years, now h<strong>as</strong> a remaining term of 4.5 years. To price the bond, we need to know<br />

the interest-rate for a term of 4.5 years.<br />

44<br />

n = 21 in our c<strong>as</strong>e.<br />

90


5.5.1 Zero-Coupon Bonds<br />

CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

We consider both – government <strong>an</strong>d corporate zero-coupon bonds.<br />

The price of a government zero-coupon bond at tk with <strong>an</strong> initial term of T years is<br />

given by 45<br />

P (tk, T, ) = exp(−R(tk, T )(T − tk)). (5.40)<br />

As we consider the government bonds to be non-defaultable, we do not have to deal with<br />

default times.<br />

In the c<strong>as</strong>e of a corporate zero-coupon bonds, we need to deal with default times<br />

τ. Of course, the procedure is exactly the same for default times generated with either<br />

a one-factor Gaussi<strong>an</strong> or NIG copula. If a default occurs before ˆ T (i.e. τ < ˆ T ), with<br />

ˆT = min(T, T sim ), the price of the zero-coupon bond at τ reduces to the recovery value<br />

RV , which is calculated <strong>as</strong> RV = 1 · REC 46 <strong>as</strong>suming a fixed recovery rate REC = 40%<br />

of the notional for every zero-coupon bond. 47 We need to compound the recovery value to<br />

the next simulation date tk. Then, we compound the value of the defaulted bond at every<br />

remaining pricing day with the 3 month government interest-rate. If no default occurs,<br />

the pricing works <strong>an</strong>alogously to a government bond. In Figure 5.7, we illustrate what<br />

happens at default.<br />

Figure 5.7: Compounding of recovery payment<br />

If a default occurs between tk−1 <strong>an</strong>d tk, we <strong>as</strong>sume the recovery payment RV to be<br />

received at τ. As this happens without <strong>an</strong>y uncertainties, we compound this payment<br />

with the risk-free government rate to the next pricing day tk. At tk the amount is then<br />

invested in a risk-free c<strong>as</strong>h account.<br />

Formally, the price of a corporate zero-coupon bond with rating R is given by<br />

⎧<br />

P d ⎪⎨<br />

(tk, T, R, τ) =<br />

⎪⎩<br />

with R d (tk, T, R) = R(tk, T ) + SR(tk, T ).<br />

exp(−R d (tk, T, R, τ)(T − tk)) , if τ > tk<br />

RV · exp(R(τ, tk)(tk − τ)) , if tk−1 < τ ≤ tk<br />

P d (tk−1, T, τ) · exp(R(tk−1, tk)(tk − tk−1)) , if τ ≤ tk−1,<br />

(5.41)<br />

For every simulated timestep tk > 0, we determine the total return of the investment,<br />

45<br />

See equation (5.1).<br />

46<br />

In general, RV is calculated according to RV = L · REC, where L denotes the notional amount.<br />

According to Remark 5.25, we <strong>as</strong>sume L = 1.<br />

47<br />

This <strong>as</strong>sumption is made for re<strong>as</strong>ons of simplicity. According to [Sta06], p. 26, the average recovery<br />

rate for senior unsecured debt is 42.6%.<br />

91


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

R P , by calculating the price ch<strong>an</strong>ge from the previous timestep, tk−1, to the current<br />

timestep, tk, <strong>an</strong>d relating it to the price in tk−1. Formally, R P c<strong>an</strong> be expressed by<br />

for a government zero-coupon bond <strong>an</strong>d by<br />

for a corporate zero-coupon bond.<br />

5.5.2 Coupon Bonds<br />

R P (tk−1, tk) = P (tk, T )<br />

− 1 (5.42)<br />

P (tk−1, T )<br />

R P (tk−1, tk, R, τ) = P d (tk, T, R, τ)<br />

P d − 1 (5.43)<br />

(tk−1, T, R, τ)<br />

We consider again government <strong>an</strong>d corporate coupon bonds <strong>an</strong>d we <strong>as</strong>sume that a coupon<br />

bond h<strong>as</strong> n coupon payment dates tc i , with coupon payments amounting to C:<br />

t c 1 < ... < t c n = T.<br />

t c 1 denotes the next coupon payment date following the current pricing day tk. At maturity<br />

T , the notional amount is also paid to the investor. 48<br />

We illustrate the possible c<strong>as</strong>h flow structure with Figure 5.8.<br />

Figure 5.8: Coupon payment structure of a coupon bond<br />

At pricing days tk, we have to discount all future c<strong>as</strong>h flows to determine the price.<br />

We begin specifying the price of a government coupon bond at simulated timestep<br />

tk ∈ � 0, ..., T sim� with <strong>an</strong> initial term of T :<br />

B(tk, T, C) =<br />

�<br />

i∈{j=1...n|t c j >tk}<br />

C · P (tk, t c i) + 1 · P (tk, T ). (5.44)<br />

We <strong>as</strong>sume that there is no default, <strong>as</strong> we consider the government bonds to be non-<br />

defaultable. P (tk, tc i ) is then calculated by equation (5.40).<br />

If we price a corporate coupon bond with rating R, we need to consider default times<br />

τ. The treatment is <strong>an</strong>alogous to that of zero-coupon bonds <strong>as</strong> described in Section 5.5.1.<br />

If a default occurs before ˆ T , with ˆ T = min(T, T sim ), the price of the coupon bond at<br />

τ reduces to the recovery value RV , which is calculated <strong>as</strong>suming a fixed recovery rate<br />

REC = 40% of the notional for every coupon bond. We need to compound the recovery<br />

value to the next simulation date tk. Then, we compound the value of the defaulted bond<br />

at every remaining pricing day with the 3 month government interest-rate. If no default<br />

48 For pricing issues, we <strong>as</strong>sume a notional amount of 1 (see Remark 5.25).<br />

92


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

occurs, the pricing works <strong>an</strong>alogously to a government bond. Formally, the price of a<br />

corporate coupon bond with rating R is given by<br />

⎧<br />

⎪⎨<br />

B(tk, T, C, R, τ) =<br />

⎪⎩<br />

�<br />

i∈{j=1...n|t c j >tk}<br />

C · P d (tk, t c i, R, τ) + 1 · P d (tk, T, R, τ), if τ > tk<br />

RV · exp(R(τ, tk)(tk − τ)), if tk−1 < τ ≤ tk<br />

B(tk−1, T, C, R, τ) · exp(R(tk−1, tk)(tk − tk−1)), if τ ≤ tk−1,<br />

(5.45)<br />

For every simulated timestep, tk > 0, we determine the total return of the investment,<br />

R B , by calculating the price ch<strong>an</strong>ge from the previous timestep, tk−1, to the current<br />

timestep, tk, adding the c<strong>as</strong>h flows in tk, i.e. the coupon payments, 49 <strong>an</strong>d then relating it<br />

to the price in tk−1. Formally, R B c<strong>an</strong> be expressed by<br />

for a government coupon bond <strong>an</strong>d by<br />

R B (tk−1, tk, C) = B(tk, T, C) + C(tk)<br />

B(tk−1, T, C)<br />

R B (tk−1, tk, C, R, τ) = B(tk, T, C, R, τ) + C(tk) · 1 {τ>tk}<br />

B(tk−1, T, C, R, τ)<br />

− 1, (5.46)<br />

− 1, (5.47)<br />

for a corporate coupon-bond. Here C(tk) denotes coupon payments coinciding with pricing<br />

day tk <strong>an</strong>d 1 {•} denotes the indicator function 50 , which is necessary <strong>as</strong> the coupon is only<br />

paid <strong>as</strong> long <strong>as</strong> no default h<strong>as</strong> occurred.<br />

5.5.3 Excursus: Default Intensity Model<br />

To price CDS <strong>an</strong>d CDS indices 51 , it is necessary to know the expected losses at every<br />

pricing day for every outst<strong>an</strong>ding spread payment date. For this purpose, we apply the<br />

const<strong>an</strong>t default intensity model, introduced in this section.<br />

In contr<strong>as</strong>t to structural models, reduced form models do not tie defaults to funda-<br />

mental data of a firm, such <strong>as</strong> the stock market capitalisation or the leverage ratio. 52<br />

They rather <strong>as</strong>sume defaults to be exogenous events that occur at unknown times τ. Fur-<br />

thermore, they are not <strong>as</strong>sumed to be directly related to the firm’s bal<strong>an</strong>ce sheet. These<br />

models w<strong>an</strong>t to <strong>as</strong>sign probabilities to different outcomes of τ.<br />

Reduced form models characterise the r<strong>an</strong>dom nature of defaults for <strong>an</strong> obligor typ-<br />

ically in terms of the first ”arrival” of defaults over time with a Poisson process. To<br />

49<br />

In our framework, the coupon payment dates coincide with simulated timesteps. Therefore, we c<strong>an</strong><br />

simply take the coupon payment for the return calculations. If, however, the coupon payment dates deviate<br />

from the pricing days, we would have to discount the payment at the risk-free rate to the next pricing day.<br />

50<br />

The indicator function is defined by<br />

�<br />

� 1 , if τ > tk<br />

1{τ>t k} =<br />

�<br />

0 , if τ ≤ tk.<br />

51<br />

The pricing procedure of funded CDS c<strong>an</strong> be found in Section 5.5.5 <strong>an</strong>d of funded CDS indices in<br />

Section 5.5.6.<br />

52<br />

For theoretical background regarding credit risk modelling, we refer for example to [DS03] or [Gie04].<br />

93


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

underst<strong>an</strong>d these processes, we first need to define the Poisson distribution <strong>an</strong>d the expo-<br />

nential distribution. 53<br />

Definition 5.26 (Poisson Distribution)<br />

A r<strong>an</strong>dom variable X follows a Poisson distribution with parameter λ > 0 (X ∼ P(λ)), if<br />

Then, P [X ≤ x] is given by<br />

P [X = x] = exp(−λ) λx<br />

, x ∈ N0.<br />

x!<br />

P [X ≤ x] =<br />

x�<br />

i=0<br />

exp(−λ) λx<br />

x! .<br />

Me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d vari<strong>an</strong>ce of a Poisson distributed r<strong>an</strong>dom variable are given by<br />

E [X] = λ <strong>an</strong>d V [X] = λ.<br />

In the context of Poisson distributions, we often see <strong>an</strong> exponential distribution 54 . If<br />

the occurrence of events follows a Poisson distribution, the time between those events is<br />

exponentially distributed. An exponential distribution is defined <strong>as</strong> follows.<br />

Definition 5.27 (Exponential Distribution)<br />

A r<strong>an</strong>dom variable X follows <strong>an</strong> exponential distribution with parameter λ > 0 (X ∼<br />

Exp(λ)), if its density function is of the form<br />

f(x) = λ exp(−λx), x ≥ 0.<br />

The corresponding distribution function h<strong>as</strong> the form<br />

F (x) = 1 − exp(−λx), x ≥ 0. (5.48)<br />

Me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d vari<strong>an</strong>ce of <strong>an</strong> exponential distributed r<strong>an</strong>dom variable are given by<br />

E [X] = 1<br />

λ<br />

Now, we c<strong>an</strong> define a Poisson process. 55<br />

Definition 5.28 (Poisson Process)<br />

<strong>an</strong>d V [X] = 1<br />

λ 2 .<br />

Let the r<strong>an</strong>dom variable X be Poisson distributed (X ∼ P(λ)), where X corresponds to<br />

the number of events occurring over a continuous time interval [0, ∞). Moreover, let the<br />

time between the occurrence of these events be independent <strong>an</strong>d exponentially distributed<br />

with distribution function (5.48) <strong>as</strong>suming that defaults occur r<strong>an</strong>domly at the me<strong>an</strong> rate<br />

(or intensity 56 ) of λ per year, with λ > 0.<br />

53<br />

For more background regarding the Poisson distribution, we refer for example to [Har95], pp. 213 or<br />

to [Kre02], p. 86.<br />

54<br />

For more background regarding the exponential distribution, we refer for example to [Har95], pp. 219<br />

55<br />

For more background regarding the Poisson processes, we refer for example to [Har95], p. 783 or<br />

[Kre02], pp. 227.<br />

56<br />

That is where the name ”default intensity model” comes from.<br />

94


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

Let Xt be the number of events which occurred in the time interval [0, t]. The stoch<strong>as</strong>tic<br />

process {Xt; t ≥ 0} is then called Poisson process with intensity λ.<br />

The probability function of {Xt} is given by<br />

P [Xt = x] = exp(−λt) (λt)x<br />

, x ∈ N0. (5.49)<br />

x!<br />

Hence, P [Xt = x] denotes the probability of exactly x defaults within a t-year time<br />

interval. Me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d vari<strong>an</strong>ce of a Poisson process are consequently given by<br />

E [X] = λt <strong>an</strong>d V [X] = λt.<br />

Let Xt be the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process, corresponding to the number of defaults arriving over<br />

a continuous time interval <strong>an</strong>d <strong>as</strong>sume that defaults occur r<strong>an</strong>domly at the me<strong>an</strong> rate of<br />

λ per year, with λ > 0. We <strong>as</strong>sume Xt to follow a Poisson process. Now, we c<strong>an</strong> e<strong>as</strong>ily<br />

calculate the unconditional probability of no defaults in a t-year time interval by setting<br />

x = 0 in equation (5.49):<br />

P [Xt = 0] = exp(−λt). (5.50)<br />

Analogously, we c<strong>an</strong> calculate the unconditional probability of exactly one default in<br />

a t-year time interval by setting x = 1 in equation (5.49):<br />

P [Xt = 1] = λt · exp(−λt). (5.51)<br />

For pricing credit derivatives, the expected time of the first default is of great inter-<br />

est. Let τ be the time of the first default, which is a continuous r<strong>an</strong>dom variable with<br />

distribution function Q(t). For Q(t) we c<strong>an</strong> write<br />

⎧<br />

⎨ P [τ ≤ t] = 1 − P [τ > t] , if t ≥ 0<br />

Q(t) =<br />

⎩<br />

0 , if t < 0.<br />

Note that P [τ > t] is the probability of no defaults by time t, which is given by equation<br />

(5.50). Thus, for t ≥ 0, we c<strong>an</strong> write<br />

Q(t) = 1 − exp(−λt). (5.52)<br />

This c<strong>an</strong> be thought of <strong>as</strong> the unconditional probability of the first default by time t.<br />

The unconditional density function of τ is defined <strong>as</strong> ∂Q(t)<br />

∂t , <strong>an</strong>d we c<strong>an</strong> write<br />

q(t) := ∂Q(t)<br />

∂t<br />

= λ exp(−λt). (5.53)<br />

Note that q(t) is the density function <strong>an</strong>d Q(t) the distribution function of <strong>an</strong> exponen-<br />

tially distributed r<strong>an</strong>dom variable. Therefore, the time of first default τ is exponentially<br />

distributed when defaults follow a Poisson process. 57<br />

57 See [Bom05], pp. 317.<br />

95


5.5.4 Floating Rate Notes<br />

CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

Now, we consider a floating rate note (FRN). We do not w<strong>an</strong>t to price FRNs <strong>as</strong> own<br />

instruments, but they will play <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t role when it comes to pricing funded CDS<br />

or funded CDS indices, respectively. In our c<strong>as</strong>e, a FRN is supposed to be risk-free. It is<br />

<strong>as</strong>sumed to have quarterly coupon payment dates tc i , with a coupon amounting to 3 month<br />

LIBOR, always determined at the previous coupon payment date, tc i−1 . At maturity T ,<br />

the nominal amount is paid to the investor, too. The coupon payment dates are given by<br />

t c 1 < ... < t c n = T.<br />

t c 1 denotes the next coupon payment date following the current pricing day tk. 58 We denote<br />

by t c 0<br />

the previous coupon payment date or settlement date, if the first coupon payment<br />

h<strong>as</strong> not yet been made. Thus, the coupon payment dates are described relative to pricing<br />

days <strong>an</strong>d therefore move with pricing days. Figure 5.9 illustrates the relation between the<br />

pricing days <strong>an</strong>d the coupon payments dates.<br />

Figure 5.9: Possible c<strong>as</strong>h flow structure of a FRN<br />

Formally this relation c<strong>an</strong> be expressed by t c 0 ≤ tk < t c 1 .<br />

In general, the price of a FRN at pricing day tk with a nominal value of 1, future<br />

coupon payments t c 1 , tc 2 , ..., tc n <strong>an</strong>d not paying a spread over the reference interest-rate 59 is<br />

given by 60<br />

F RN(tk, t c 0, T ) = P (tk, t c 1 )<br />

P (t c 0 , tc 1 ) − P (tk, T ) + P (tk, T )<br />

where P (•, •) is calculated by equation (5.40).<br />

= P (tk, tc 1 )<br />

P (tc 0 , tc , (5.54)<br />

1 )<br />

Funded CDS <strong>an</strong>d funded CDS indices pay LIBOR on the notional amount. Actually,<br />

LIBOR is a linear interest-rate 61 <strong>an</strong>d h<strong>as</strong> a small spread over the risk-free government<br />

rate. For the sake of simplicity, however, we use the simulated 3 month government rate<br />

representing LIBOR, i.e. the continuous rate is used <strong>as</strong> linear rate <strong>an</strong>d the rate does<br />

not contain the spread above the risk-free rate, usually observed for the LIBOR. This<br />

procedure is the same for all CDS <strong>an</strong>d CDS indices, so that the qualitative conclusions<br />

from our <strong>an</strong>alyses remain unch<strong>an</strong>ged.<br />

In our simulation <strong>an</strong>d pricing framework, the price of a FRN at tk with a nominal<br />

58 Hence, we allow coupon payment dates not to coincide with pricing days.<br />

59 LIBOR c<strong>an</strong>, for example, be such a reference rate.<br />

60 See [Zag02], pp. 182-184.<br />

61 See Definition 5.1.<br />

96


value of 1 is then determined according to 62<br />

CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

F RN(tk, t c 0, T ) = (1 + R(t c 0, t c 0 + ∆t c 1) · ∆t c 1) · P (tk, t c 1), (5.55)<br />

where (1 + R(tc 0 , tc0 + ∆tc1 ) · ∆tc 1<br />

1 ) corresponds to<br />

5.5.5 Funded CDS<br />

P (tc 0 ,tc 1 ) in equation (5.54).<br />

We consider CDS from a protection seller’s perspective. Hence we consider CDS <strong>as</strong> invest-<br />

ment rather th<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong> a me<strong>an</strong>s of hedging. 63 In order to ensure a comparability to bonds,<br />

we use funded CDS.<br />

Before explaining the return components of a funded CDS, we briefly describe the<br />

relation of the relev<strong>an</strong>t timesteps. At every simulated timestep tk ∈ � 0, ..., T sim� we price<br />

the funded CDS. Furthermore, we <strong>as</strong>sume that<br />

t c 1 < ... < t c n = T<br />

denote the spread payment dates, where tc 1 denotes the next spread payment date following<br />

the current pricing day tk <strong>an</strong>d T denotes the maturity of the CDS. We denote by tc 0 the<br />

previous spread payment date or settlement date, if the first spread payment h<strong>as</strong> not<br />

yet been made. Formally this c<strong>an</strong> be expressed by tc 0 ≤ tk < tc 1 . For <strong>an</strong> illustration of<br />

the relation of coupon payment dates <strong>an</strong>d pricing days, we refer to Figure 5.9. Spread<br />

payments are made in arrear – at time t c i for the payment period from tc i−1 to tc i .<br />

A funded CDS h<strong>as</strong> the following return components:<br />

• Present value of the CDS for every pricing day tk, P VCDS, resulting from possible<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the default intensity λk at tk, 64<br />

• present value of the pure, default risk-free FRN at tk, P VF RN, paying LIBOR,<br />

• coupon payments on the notional amount at tc 0 , comprising LIBOR <strong>an</strong>d the fixed<br />

spread s, compounded to the following simulated date tk, P Vs (see Figure 5.10),<br />

• recovery payments at default time τ, compounded to the following simulated date<br />

tk, P VREC (see Figure 5.11). 65<br />

For the pricing of a funded CDS, we partly follow [KSW05] adjusting the pricing<br />

formul<strong>as</strong> to our needs.<br />

To determine the present value of the funded CDS at tk, we need to know the expected<br />

loss at tk up to every spread payment day t c i , i ∈ {1, ..., n}, EL(tk, t c i , λk), the premium<br />

leg, Premium Leg(tk, T, s, λk), <strong>an</strong>d the protection leg, Protection Leg(tk, T, λk), which are<br />

described below.<br />

62 In our c<strong>as</strong>e, ∆t c i = 0.25 <strong>as</strong> we <strong>as</strong>sume quarterly coupon payments.<br />

63 The functionality of a funded CDS is described in Section 3.2, paragraph ”Product Variations”.<br />

64 At inception of a funded CDS, the fixed spread is determined so that P VCDS is equal to zero. During<br />

the term of the funded CDS contract, however, it also c<strong>an</strong> be positive or negative, depending on the default<br />

intensity λk at tk.<br />

65 In contr<strong>as</strong>t, the recovery value is already contained in the pricing formul<strong>as</strong> of the bonds, in the c<strong>as</strong>e<br />

of corporate bonds. (See Sections 5.5.1 <strong>an</strong>d 5.5.2.)<br />

97


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

Figure 5.10: Coupon payment structure of a CDS<br />

Figure 5.11: Compounding of recovery payment<br />

The calculation of EL(tk, t c i , λk) is done by applying the const<strong>an</strong>t default intensity<br />

model <strong>as</strong> introduced in Section 5.5.3, where we <strong>as</strong>sume a const<strong>an</strong>t default intensity λk for<br />

every pricing day tk. Then, the expected loss at tk up to t c i<br />

equation (5.56)<br />

is calculated according to<br />

EL(tk, t c i, λk) = 1 − exp(−λk(t c i − tk)). (5.56)<br />

Later in this section, we explain how to determine λk.<br />

The premium leg is the present value of all expected spread payments. It is calculated<br />

according to<br />

Premium Leg(tk, T, s, λk) =<br />

n�<br />

∆t c i · s · (1 − EL (tk, t c i, λk)) · P (tk, t c i), (5.57)<br />

i=1<br />

where ∆tc i = tci −tci−1 , s is the fixed <strong>an</strong>nual spread of the series <strong>an</strong>d P (tk, tc i ) is the discount<br />

factor calculated by equation (5.40). EL (tk, tc i , λk) is the expected loss up to tc i . Then,<br />

(1 − EL(tk, tc i , λk)) = exp(−λk(tc i − tk)) denotes the probability of no default up to time<br />

t c i .<br />

Analogously, the protection leg is the present value of all expected protection payments<br />

made by the protection seller. In c<strong>as</strong>e of zero recovery, we c<strong>an</strong> calculate it by<br />

Protection Leg(tk, T, λk) =<br />

≈<br />

� T<br />

tk<br />

P (tk, l)dEL(tk, l, λk)<br />

n� �<br />

EL(tk, t c i, λk) − EL(tk, t c i−1, λk) � P (tk, t c i). (5.58)<br />

i=1<br />

98


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

However, if we <strong>as</strong>sume a const<strong>an</strong>t recovery rate of REC = 40% 66 , we calculate the<br />

protection leg by<br />

Protection Leg(tk, T, λk) =<br />

≈<br />

� T<br />

tk<br />

P (tk, l)dEL(tk, l, λk)(1 − REC)<br />

n� �<br />

EL(tk, t c i, λk) − EL(tk, t c i−1, λk) � ·<br />

i=1<br />

·P (tk, t c i) · (1 − REC). (5.59)<br />

At issu<strong>an</strong>ce of the funded CDS, the fixed <strong>an</strong>nual spread s is determined so that the<br />

value of the premium leg equals the value of the protection leg. In c<strong>as</strong>e of zero recovery<br />

this c<strong>an</strong> be formally expressed by<br />

or by<br />

s =<br />

�n i=1<br />

�<br />

EL(tk, tc i , λk) − EL(tk, tc i−1 , λk) � P (tk, tc i )<br />

�n i=1 ∆tc i · (1 − EL (tk, tc i , λk)) · P (tk, tc i )<br />

, (5.60)<br />

�n �<br />

i=1 EL(t0, t<br />

s =<br />

c i , λk) − EL(t0, tc i−1 , λk) � P (t0, tc i )(1 − REC)<br />

�n i=1 ∆tc i · (1 − EL (tk, tc i , λk)) · P (tk, tc i )<br />

, (5.61)<br />

if we <strong>as</strong>sume a fix recovery rate REC.<br />

The equality of premium leg <strong>an</strong>d protection leg, however, must also hold for every<br />

day, when s is substituted by the quoted market spread. Substituting s by the simulated<br />

spread with rating R, SR(tk, T ) 67 , at every pricing day tk in equations (5.60) or (5.61),<br />

respectively, we c<strong>an</strong> solve them for λk. This is how we determine the const<strong>an</strong>t default<br />

intensity at tk, which is necessary to calculate the present value of the funded CDS at<br />

every pricing day tk.<br />

The notional amount of a funded CDS at different timesteps tk c<strong>an</strong> either be 1, if the<br />

reference entity h<strong>as</strong> not defaulted up to tk, or 0, in c<strong>as</strong>e of default up to time tk. We<br />

denote the notional amount at each simulation date by N(tk, τ). Formally, we c<strong>an</strong> express<br />

the value of the notional amount at tk by<br />

where 1 {•} denotes the indicator function 68 .<br />

N(tk, τ) = 1 {τ>tk}, (5.62)<br />

The pricing of the first return component, P VCDS(tk, T, s, λk, τ), the present value of<br />

the CDS, is then done by<br />

P VCDS(tk, T, s, λk, τ) = (Premium Leg(tk, T, s, λk) − Protection Leg(tk, T, λk)) · N(tk, τ),<br />

(5.63)<br />

where we calculate the premium leg <strong>an</strong>d the protection leg according to equations (5.57)<br />

<strong>an</strong>d (5.58), respectively.<br />

A funded CDS receives besides the fixed quarterly spread, s∆tc i , a quarterly coupon<br />

payment with a floating interest-rate amounting to 3 month LIBOR at the l<strong>as</strong>t coupon<br />

payment date tc i−1 . The value of this instrument w<strong>as</strong> described in Section 5.5.4.<br />

66 We also <strong>as</strong>sumed a const<strong>an</strong>t recovery rate of 40% for corporate bonds for every rating cl<strong>as</strong>s.<br />

67 We use the same spread for corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d for funded CDS with the same rating cl<strong>as</strong>s.<br />

68 See equation (5.48).<br />

99


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

We take this interest-rate from our simulation by regarding the 3 month government<br />

rate <strong>as</strong> the corresponding LIBOR. 69 As LIBOR for the first coupon payment we take the<br />

LIBOR <strong>as</strong> of 20 th of September, 2006. Then, the present value of the FRN for every tk,<br />

P VF RN(tk, tc 0 , T, τ), is calculated according to<br />

P VF RN(tk, t c 0, T, τ) = F RN(tk, t c 0, T ) · N(tk, τ), (5.64)<br />

i.e. the FRN h<strong>as</strong> a present value of zero, if the reference entity defaulted.<br />

As we have seen from Figure 5.9, t c 0<br />

is the relev<strong>an</strong>t coupon payment date for pricing<br />

day tk. In c<strong>as</strong>e of default, we <strong>as</strong>sume a proportional coupon payment <strong>as</strong> the funded CDS<br />

contract is <strong>as</strong>sumed to be similar to <strong>an</strong> insur<strong>an</strong>ce contract. During the period between<br />

the l<strong>as</strong>t coupon payment, the protection seller guar<strong>an</strong>teed to carry a default-related loss.<br />

Therefore, he is to be compensated for this guar<strong>an</strong>tee by a proportional coupon payment,<br />

too. For this re<strong>as</strong>on it is necessary to consider the coupon payment date prior to t c 0 :<br />

t c −1 :=<br />

⎧<br />

⎪⎨<br />

⎪⎩<br />

∅ , if k = 0<br />

t0 , if k = 1<br />

t c −1 , if k > 1.<br />

To allow for a proportional coupon payment, if a default h<strong>as</strong> taken place between t c −1<br />

<strong>an</strong>d t c 0 , we introduce a time-weighted notional amount at the coupon payment date, tc 0 ,<br />

N t (tk, tc 0 , τ), which is given by<br />

N t (tk, t c 0, τ) =<br />

⎧<br />

⎪⎨<br />

⎪⎩<br />

0 , if k = 0<br />

0 , if τ ≤ t c −1<br />

τ−tc −1<br />

∆tc 0<br />

1 , if τ > tc 0 .<br />

, if t c −1 < τ ≤ tc 0<br />

Now we c<strong>an</strong> describe the coupon payments the investor receives at the coupon payment<br />

date tc 0 , C(tk, tc 0 , s, τ). They consist of 3 month LIBOR <strong>an</strong>d the fixed spread s on the<br />

weighted notional amount N t (tk, tc 0 , τ). At maturity, the investor additionally receives the<br />

actual notional amount N(T, τ). Then, the c<strong>as</strong>h flows from the investment at t c 0<br />

by<br />

⎧<br />

C(tk, t c ⎪⎨<br />

0, s, τ) =<br />

⎪⎩<br />

0 , if k = 0<br />

(s + R(t c −1 , tc −1 + ∆tc 0 )) · ∆tc 0 · N t (tk, t c 0 , τ) , if tk < T<br />

are given<br />

(s + R(tc −1 , tc−1 + ∆tc0 )) · ∆tc0 · N t (tk, tc 0 , τ) + N(T, τ) , if tc0 = T<br />

0 , if tk+1 > T.<br />

(5.65)<br />

In order to determine the present value of that payment at the next simulated timestep<br />

tk, P Vs(tk, tc 0 , s, τ), we need to compound C(tk, tc 0 , s, τ). This principle is shown in Figure<br />

5.10. Formally, the compounding is calculated <strong>as</strong><br />

P Vs(tk, t c 0, s, τ) = C(tk, t c 0, s, τ) exp(R(t c 0, tk)(tk − t c 0)). (5.66)<br />

69 This is done for the sake of simplicity. For a brief discussion on implications, we refer to Section 5.5.4.<br />

100


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

Recovery payments are the l<strong>as</strong>t return component. Regarding a funded CDS, the<br />

protection seller receives a recovery payment at default time τ. On the other h<strong>an</strong>d, the<br />

contract terminates. A default occurring before ˆ T (i.e. τ < ˆ T ), with ˆ T = min(T, T sim ),<br />

h<strong>as</strong> to be treated in the following way: The investor receives the recovery value RV , which<br />

is calculated <strong>as</strong> RV = 1 · REC <strong>as</strong>suming a fixed recovery rate of REC = 40% in the c<strong>as</strong>e<br />

of default. We need to compound the recovery payment to the next simulation date tk.<br />

Then, the value of the defaulted funded CDS h<strong>as</strong> to be compounded at every remaining<br />

pricing day. Formally, this is done with the following equation, <strong>an</strong>alogous to the procedure<br />

already described for corporate (zero-) coupon bonds:<br />

⎧<br />

⎪⎨<br />

P VREC(tk, τ) =<br />

⎪⎩<br />

0 , if τ > tk<br />

RV · exp(R(τ, tk)(tk − τ)) , if tk−1 < τ ≤ tk<br />

P VREC(tk−1, τ) · exp(R(tk−1, tk)(tk − tk−1)) , if τ ≤ tk−1,<br />

(5.67)<br />

We define the value of a CDS investment for every timestep tk, CDS(tk, T, s, λk, τ),<br />

containing all return components apart from the present value of the spread payments<br />

P Vs by 70<br />

CDS(tk, T, s, λk, τ) = P VCDS(tk, T, s, λk, τ)+P VF RN(tk, t c 0, T, τ)+P VREC(tk, τ). (5.68)<br />

For every simulated timestep tk > 0, we determine the total return of the investment,<br />

R CDS , by calculating the ch<strong>an</strong>ge in value from the previous timestep, tk−1, to the current<br />

timestep, tk, adding the compounded coupon payments paid between tk−1 <strong>an</strong>d tk <strong>an</strong>d then<br />

relating it to the value in tk−1. 71 Formally, R CDS c<strong>an</strong> be expressed by<br />

R CDS (tk−1, tk) = CDS(tk) + P Vs(tk)<br />

CDS(tk−1)<br />

− 1. (5.69)<br />

For simplicity re<strong>as</strong>ons, we omitted all input parameters for the single pricing components<br />

apart from the pricing day.<br />

5.5.6 Funded CDS Indices<br />

Now, we consider CDS indices. We take again the perspective of a protection seller<br />

considering funded CDS indices <strong>as</strong> investment rather th<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong> me<strong>an</strong>s of hedging. In order to<br />

ensure a comparability to government <strong>an</strong>d corporate bonds, we use funded CDS indices. 72<br />

We think of a CDS index <strong>as</strong> a large homogeneous portfolio <strong>as</strong> given in Definition<br />

5.18. Then, we c<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>sume <strong>an</strong> average default intensity <strong>an</strong>d thus, we c<strong>an</strong> apply the same<br />

formul<strong>as</strong> <strong>as</strong> for CDS. These formul<strong>as</strong> were already introduced in Section 5.5.5. 73 We will<br />

70<br />

This definition is <strong>an</strong>alogue to the definition of the price of a corporate coupon bond (see equation<br />

(5.45)), which also contains all return components apart from the coupon payments.<br />

71<br />

The return calculation is done <strong>an</strong>alogously to the return calculation of a corporate coupon bond (see<br />

equation (5.47)).<br />

72<br />

We already described the functionality of both funded <strong>an</strong>d unfunded CDS indices in Section 3.9.<br />

73<br />

There, we partly followed [KSW05] adjusting the pricing formul<strong>as</strong> to our needs.<br />

101


epeat the adjusted formul<strong>as</strong> here in short.<br />

Let us <strong>as</strong>sume that<br />

denote the spread payment dates, where t c 1<br />

CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

t c 1 < ... < t c n = T<br />

denotes the next spread payment date following<br />

the current pricing day tk <strong>an</strong>d T denotes the maturity of the funded CDS index. 74<br />

At first, we describe the return components of a funded CDS index, which is priced at<br />

every simulated timestep tk ∈ � 0, ..., T sim� :<br />

• Present value of the funded CDS index for every pricing day tk, P Vindex, resulting<br />

from possible ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the default intensity λk at tk, 75 ,<br />

• present value of the pure, default risk-free FRN at tk, P VF RN, paying LIBOR,<br />

• coupon payments on the notional amount at tc 0 , comprising LIBOR <strong>an</strong>d the fixed<br />

spread s76 , compounded to the following simulated date tk, P Vs (see Figure 5.10),<br />

• recovery payments at default times τ, compounded to the following simulated date<br />

tk, P VREC (see Figure 5.11). 77<br />

To determine the present value of the funded CDS index at tk, we need to know the<br />

expected loss at tk up to every spread payment day t c i , i ∈ {1, ..., n}, EL(tk, t c i , λk), the<br />

premium leg, Premium Leg(tk, T, s, λk), <strong>an</strong>d the protection leg, Protection Leg(tk, T, λk),<br />

which are described below.<br />

Applying the const<strong>an</strong>t default intensity model <strong>as</strong> introduced in Section 5.5.3, the ex-<br />

pected loss of a large homogeneous portfolio at tk up to every spread payment day t c i ,<br />

EL(tk, t c i , λk) is given by equation (5.56)<br />

EL(tk, t c i, λk) = 1 − exp(−λk(t c i − tk)).<br />

Here, λk is determined in the same way <strong>as</strong> for funded CDS.<br />

We calculate the premium leg <strong>an</strong>d the protection leg <strong>an</strong>alogous to CDS. Therefore, the<br />

premium leg is calculated according to equation (5.57)<br />

Premium Leg(tk, T, s, λk) =<br />

n�<br />

∆t c i · s · (1 − EL (tk, t c i, λk)) · P (tk, t c i),<br />

i=1<br />

where ∆tc i = tci − tci−1 , s is the fixed <strong>an</strong>nual spread of the series, P (tk, tc i ) is the discount<br />

factor <strong>an</strong>d EL (tk, tc i , λk) is the expected loss calculated by equation (5.56).<br />

Assuming a const<strong>an</strong>t recovery rate REC, we c<strong>an</strong> calculate the protection leg by equa-<br />

74<br />

For more information, we refer to Section 5.5.5.<br />

75<br />

At inception of a funded CDS index, the fixed spread is determined so that P Vindex is equal to zero.<br />

During the term of the funded CDS index contract, however, it also c<strong>an</strong> be positive or negative, depending<br />

on the default intensity λk at tk.<br />

76<br />

As explained in Section 3.9, there is one fixed spread for the index, representing a kind of average<br />

spread for the portfolio of reference entities.<br />

77<br />

In the c<strong>as</strong>e of corporate bonds, the recovery value is already contained in the pricing formul<strong>as</strong> of the<br />

bonds. (See Sections 5.5.1 <strong>an</strong>d 5.5.2.)<br />

102


tion (5.59)<br />

Protection Leg(tk, T, λk) =<br />

CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

≈<br />

� T<br />

tk<br />

P (tk, l)dEL(tk, l, λk)(1 − REC)<br />

n� �<br />

EL(tk, t c i, λk) − EL(tk, t c i−1, λk) � P (tk, t c i)(1 − REC).<br />

i=1<br />

For pricing funded CDS indices at different timesteps tk, it is essential to know the<br />

notional amount of the reference portfolio. At simulation start date, we <strong>as</strong>sume the no-<br />

tional to be one. Furthermore, we <strong>as</strong>sume a portfolio with 125 equally weighted reference<br />

entities. Thus, every title in the portfolio h<strong>as</strong> a weight of 0.8%. This is the weight by<br />

which the notional amount h<strong>as</strong> to be reduced at the time of a default τ. Let τk be a vector<br />

containing all default times occurred after tk−1 <strong>an</strong>d up to tk with size (l × 1). We denote<br />

the notional amount at each simulation date by N(tk, τk). Then, we c<strong>an</strong> formally express<br />

the value of the notional amount at tk by<br />

N(tk, τk) = N(tk−1, τk−1) − 0.8% · l. (5.70)<br />

Now, we c<strong>an</strong> price the first return component, the present value of the index, which is<br />

done <strong>an</strong>alogously to equation (5.63):<br />

P Vindex(tk, T, s, λk, τk) = (Premium Leg(tk, T, s, λk)−Protection Leg(tk, T, λk))·N(tk, τk),<br />

(5.71)<br />

where we calculate the premium leg <strong>an</strong>d the protection leg according to equations (5.57)<br />

<strong>an</strong>d (5.59), respectively.<br />

As described in Section 3.9, a funded CDS index receives besides the fixed quarterly<br />

spread, s∆tc i , a quarterly coupon payment with a floating interest-rate amounting to 3<br />

month LIBOR at the l<strong>as</strong>t coupon payment date tc i−1 . The value of this instrument w<strong>as</strong><br />

described in Section 5.5.4.<br />

We take this interest-rate from our simulations by regarding the 3 month government<br />

rate <strong>as</strong> the corresponding LIBOR. As LIBOR for the first coupon payment we take the<br />

LIBOR <strong>as</strong> of 20 th of September, 2006. Then, the present value of the FRN for every tk,<br />

P VF RN(tk, t c 0 , T, τk), is calculated according to equation (5.64)<br />

P VF RN(tk, t c 0, T, τk) = F RN(tk, t c 0, T ) · N(tk, τk). (5.72)<br />

Analogous to funded CDS, we introduce a time-weighted notional amount at each<br />

coupon payment date t c 0 , N t (tk, t c 0 , τ ∗ ) 78 , where τ ∗ is a vector containing all default times. 79<br />

If defaults have taken place between tc −1 (coupon payment prior to tc0 )80 <strong>an</strong>d tc 0 , we <strong>as</strong>sume<br />

a proportional coupon payment.<br />

As already seen, the investor receives a payment, C(tk, t c 0 , s, τ ∗ ), consisting of 3 month<br />

LIBOR <strong>an</strong>d the fixed spread s on the notional amount N t (tk, t c 0 , τ ∗ ), at the coupon pay-<br />

78 An expl<strong>an</strong>ation for this procedure c<strong>an</strong> be found in Section 5.5.5. The calculation is similar to the<br />

calculation of the time-weighted notional amount for funded CDS, <strong>as</strong> described in the previous section.<br />

79 For one scenario, the vector h<strong>as</strong> the size (125 × 1), <strong>as</strong> every reference entity in the reference portfolio<br />

h<strong>as</strong> its own default time.<br />

80 For a definition, ple<strong>as</strong>e refer to Section 5.5.5.<br />

103


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

ment date tc 0 . At maturity, the investor additionally receives the actual notional amount<br />

at maturity date, N(T, τ ∗ ). Then, the regular c<strong>as</strong>h flows from the investment at tc 0 are<br />

similar to equation (5.65)<br />

C(tk, t c 0, s, τ ∗ ) =<br />

⎧<br />

⎪⎨<br />

⎪⎩<br />

0 , if k = 0<br />

(s + R(t c −1 , tc −1 + ∆tc 0 )) · ∆tc 0 · N t (tk, t c 0 , τ ∗ ) , if tk < T<br />

(s + R(tc −1 , tc−1 + ∆tc0 )) · ∆tc0 · N t (tk, tc 0 , τ ∗ ) + N(T, τ ∗ ) , if tc 0 = T<br />

0 , if tk+1 > T.<br />

(5.73)<br />

In order to determine the present value of that payment at the next simulated timestep<br />

tk, P Vs(tk, t c i , s, τ ∗ ), we need to compound C(tk, t c 0 , s, τ ∗ ). For <strong>an</strong> illustration of this prin-<br />

ciple, we refer to Figure 5.10.<br />

Formally, the compounding is calculated by equation (5.66)<br />

P Vs(tk, t c 0, s, τ ∗ ) = C(tk, t c 0, s, τ ∗ ) exp(R(t c 0, tk)(tk − t c 0)). (5.74)<br />

Recovery payments are the l<strong>as</strong>t return component. Regarding a funded CDS index,<br />

the protection seller receives a recovery payment at default of a reference entity <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

notional amount is reduced by 0.8% for every default. Each default that occurred before<br />

ˆT with ˆ T = min(T, T sim ), h<strong>as</strong> to be treated in the following way: The investor receives<br />

the recovery value RV , which is calculated <strong>as</strong> RV = 0.8% · REC with a fixed recovery<br />

rate of REC = 40%. We need to compound each recovery payment received between tk−1<br />

<strong>an</strong>d tk to the next simulation date tk. This calculation h<strong>as</strong> to be done for every element<br />

τk,j, j ∈ {1, ..., l}, of τk. The results have to be summed up. Recovery payments received<br />

before tk−1 have to be compounded to tk <strong>an</strong>d added to the latest recovery payments. This<br />

principle is illustrated in Figure 5.12.<br />

Figure 5.12: Compounding of recovery payments of a CDS index<br />

Formally, we express the present value of the recovery payments by<br />

104


CHAPTER 5. SIMULATION AND PRICING FRAMEWORK<br />

⎧<br />

⎪⎩<br />

0, if k = 0<br />

P VREC(tk, τ ∗ ⎪⎨<br />

0, if τ<br />

) =<br />

∗ > tk<br />

P VREC(tk−1, τ ∗ ) · exp(R(tk−1, tk)(tk − tk−1))+<br />

+ � l<br />

j=1 RV · exp(R(τk,j, tk)(tk − τk,j)).<br />

(5.75)<br />

Analogous to equation (5.68), we calculate the value of <strong>an</strong> investment into a funded<br />

CDS index for every simulated timestep tk, CDSindex(tk, T, s, λk, τk), containing all return<br />

components apart from the present value of the spread payments P Vs, by<br />

CDSindex(tk, T, s, λk, τk) = P Vindex(tk, T, s, λk, τk)+P VF RN(tk, t c 0, T, τk)+P VREC(tk, τ ∗ ).<br />

(5.76)<br />

For every simulated timestep tk > 0, we determine the total return of the investment<br />

R CDSindex, by calculating the ch<strong>an</strong>ge in value from the previous timestep, tk−1, to the<br />

current timestep, tk, adding the compounded coupon payments paid between tk−1 <strong>an</strong>d tk<br />

<strong>an</strong>d then relating it to the value in tk−1. Formally, R CDSindex c<strong>an</strong> be expressed by<br />

R CDSindex (tk−1, tk) = CDSindex(tk) + P Vs(tk)<br />

CDSindex(tk−1)<br />

− 1. (5.77)<br />

For simplicity re<strong>as</strong>ons, we also omitted all input parameters for the pricing elements apart<br />

from the pricing day.<br />

Now, we have a framework to simulate the necessary risk factors (interest-rates, credit<br />

spreads, a spread of a CDS index <strong>an</strong>d equity returns) <strong>an</strong>d a framework to price different<br />

(credit) instruments, even taking into account potential defaults. So, we obtain return<br />

distributions of the relev<strong>an</strong>t instruments, which are the starting point for portfolio opti-<br />

misations. Different optimisation criteria are introduced <strong>an</strong>d discussed in the following<br />

chapter.<br />

105


Chapter 6<br />

Portfolio Selection<br />

After having generated return distributions <strong>as</strong> described in Chapter 5, we are now inter-<br />

ested in optimal portfolios containing credit instruments. For this re<strong>as</strong>on, this chapter<br />

deals with portfolio selection. At first, we introduce the traditional portfolio selection ac-<br />

cording to Markowitz <strong>an</strong>d illuminate problems due to strict <strong>as</strong>sumptions on the structure<br />

of <strong>as</strong>set returns or utility functions. As we have seen in previous chapters, returns from<br />

credit instruments are not normally distributed. Hence, other optimisation approaches are<br />

more appropriate to take into account the distribution characteristics of such instruments.<br />

Therefore, we introduce the conditional value at risk in Section 6.2. This is roughly speak-<br />

ing the expected value of all losses exceeding a certain signific<strong>an</strong>ce level. The perform<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

me<strong>as</strong>ure Ω is presented in Section 6.3. It relates the potential upside of a portfolio’s return<br />

to its potential downside. Ω is applied to determine the risk-aversion of a certain investor<br />

if the portfolio selection criteria is the me<strong>as</strong>ure score. This is described in Section 6.4.<br />

We <strong>as</strong>sume the following preconditions for all optimisation frameworks introduced in<br />

this chapter:<br />

Remark 6.1<br />

For all optimisation frameworks, it is <strong>as</strong>sumed that<br />

• there are neither tr<strong>an</strong>saction costs nor taxes,<br />

• all securities c<strong>an</strong> be divided arbitrarily,<br />

• the portfolios remain unch<strong>an</strong>ged over time.<br />

6.1 Traditional Portfolio Selection<br />

The cl<strong>as</strong>sical portfolio theory is b<strong>as</strong>ed on the model of Markowitz. 1 The b<strong>as</strong>ic <strong>as</strong>sumption<br />

is that investors select their portfolios taking into account only the first two moments of<br />

the <strong>as</strong>set’s return – me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d vari<strong>an</strong>ce – <strong>an</strong>d the correlation between the <strong>as</strong>sets. The<br />

model is described in more detail below.<br />

6.1.1 Me<strong>an</strong>-Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Approach<br />

The central statements of Markowitz are the following. 2<br />

1 See [Mar52].<br />

2 See [SB00], p. 6.<br />

106


CHAPTER 6. PORTFOLIO SELECTION<br />

• Portfolio selection is b<strong>as</strong>ed on expected returns <strong>an</strong>d vari<strong>an</strong>ce (<strong>as</strong> me<strong>as</strong>ure of risk).<br />

• It is sensible to construct portfolios, in order to reduce risk. Correlation is the key<br />

to risk reduction.<br />

• Portfolios are denoted <strong>as</strong> ”efficient”<br />

– if there is no other portfolio with the same expected return, but with a lower<br />

risk, or<br />

– if there is no other portfolio with the same risk, but with a higher expected<br />

return.<br />

In order to formally introduce the portfolio selection according to Markowitz, we need<br />

a few definitions first. We <strong>as</strong>sume n given <strong>as</strong>sets to invest in with returns Ri, i = 1, ..., n,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d denote the<br />

• expected return of <strong>as</strong>set i by µi := E[Ri] <strong>an</strong>d µ := (µ1, ..., µn) T ,<br />

• covari<strong>an</strong>ce matrix by C = (cij)i,j=1,...,n, where cij = Cov[Ri, Rj], i, j = 1, ..., n, 3<br />

• vari<strong>an</strong>ce V[R i ] = cii =: σ 2 i<br />

> 0, i, j = 1, ..., n,4<br />

• correlation matrix Γ = (ρij)i,j=1,...,n. 5<br />

Let xi be the portfolio weight of <strong>as</strong>set i with<br />

n�<br />

xi = 1.<br />

i=1<br />

Then, we denote the portfolio by x := (x1, ..., xn) T .<br />

If there are n <strong>as</strong>sets to invest in, the expected portfolio return µ(x) is calculated <strong>as</strong><br />

weighted sum of the n expected <strong>as</strong>set returns µi, with the weight xi<br />

µ(x) = E[R(x)] =<br />

n�<br />

xiµi = µ T x.<br />

i=1<br />

The vari<strong>an</strong>ce of the portfolio return σ(x) 2 is given by<br />

σ(x) 2 := V[R(x)] =<br />

=<br />

n�<br />

i=1 j=1<br />

n�<br />

xixjcij = x T Cx.<br />

n�<br />

x 2 i · σ 2 i + 2<br />

i=1<br />

n�<br />

n�<br />

i=1 j=i+1<br />

xixjρijσiσj.<br />

The efficient frontier is the boundary of all µ(x)-σ(x)-combinations, which are not<br />

dominated by other <strong>as</strong>set weights xi of the n <strong>as</strong>sets. If µ(x)-σ(x) lies on the efficient<br />

frontier, then for a given σ(x), there is no portfolio with a higher µ(x), <strong>an</strong>d for a given<br />

3 The covari<strong>an</strong>ce is defined in equation (5.10) in Section 5.2.<br />

4 The vari<strong>an</strong>ce is defined in equation (5.7) in Section 5.2.<br />

5 The correlation is defined in equation (5.9) in Section 5.2.<br />

107


CHAPTER 6. PORTFOLIO SELECTION<br />

µ(x) there is no portfolio with a lower σ(x). The efficient frontier, with no short sales<br />

allowed, is determined according to the following optimisation problem.<br />

where 1 = (1, . . . , 1) T .<br />

min<br />

x<br />

xT Cx (6.1)<br />

s.t. µ T x ≥ µ<br />

1 T x = 1<br />

x ≥ 0,<br />

If we solve the optimisation problem (6.1) for every possible µ, we obtain the set of all<br />

efficient portfolios. Displayed in a µ(x)-σ(x)-diagram, we see the efficient frontier, such <strong>as</strong><br />

in Figure 6.1.<br />

Figure 6.1: Efficient frontier<br />

The portfolio on the efficient frontier with the lowest vari<strong>an</strong>ce is called minimum-<br />

vari<strong>an</strong>ce portfolio (MVP).<br />

In order to come to <strong>an</strong> optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocation for a certain investor, further tools<br />

like utility functions have to be applied. They imply a certain amount of utility to risk-<br />

return combinations for <strong>an</strong> investor. Applied to a certain efficient frontier, maximising the<br />

expected utility leads to a unique optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocation. 6<br />

tion.<br />

There are two main re<strong>as</strong>ons that justify the framework of Markowitz for <strong>as</strong>set alloca-<br />

First, if <strong>an</strong> investor h<strong>as</strong> a quadratic utility function, he decides in accord<strong>an</strong>ce with the<br />

µ(x)-σ(x) criteria, independent from the return distributions.<br />

Second, if the distribution of security returns <strong>an</strong>d of portfolio returns are completely<br />

determined by their me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d vari<strong>an</strong>ce, the traditional portfolio selection is valid for<br />

arbitrary utility functions. This is the c<strong>as</strong>e for normally distributed <strong>as</strong>set returns. If the<br />

marginal distributions of <strong>as</strong>set returns are normal, the resulting portfolio distribution is<br />

normal, too.<br />

6 For <strong>an</strong> introduction into utility theory, we refer for example to [BC04].<br />

108


CHAPTER 6. PORTFOLIO SELECTION<br />

Thus, if either the investor h<strong>as</strong> a quadratic utility function or if the <strong>as</strong>set returns are<br />

normally distributed, the portfolio selection according to Markowitz is appropriate.<br />

Often, the <strong>as</strong>sumptions of the framework of Markowitz are too restrictive. Problems<br />

that may arise are discussed in the next subsection. Still, the me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce approach<br />

builds the foundation of the modern capital market theory.<br />

6.1.2 Problems<br />

Quadratic utility functions only take into account the first <strong>an</strong>d the second moment of<br />

a return distribution. They do not incorporate higher moments such <strong>as</strong> skewness <strong>an</strong>d<br />

kurtosis. 7 In literature, however, one c<strong>an</strong> find empirical evidence on investor’s preference<br />

towards a positive skewness. 8 Thus, it is not appropriate to justify the application of the<br />

me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce approach by quadratic utility functions.<br />

Therefore, we now concentrate on the second justification using the me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

approach – the normal distribution of <strong>as</strong>set returns which is the st<strong>an</strong>dard approach to<br />

portfolio selection. Often, the hypothesis of normally distributed returns h<strong>as</strong> to be rejected<br />

for <strong>as</strong>set returns, particularly for fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments which c<strong>an</strong> suffer from defaults such<br />

<strong>as</strong> lowly rated bonds.<br />

In Chapter 4, for example, we showed that neither the US Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates nor the<br />

Euro-Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregates have normally distritbuted returns.<br />

To overcome this drawback, we introduce two more optimisation approaches taking<br />

into account the complete distribution <strong>an</strong>d the tail distribution, respectively.<br />

6.2 Conditional Value at Risk Optimisation<br />

Before introducing the concept of the conditional value at risk, we briefly introduce the<br />

value at risk concept.<br />

6.2.1 A Note on Value at Risk<br />

A very popular risk me<strong>as</strong>ure is the value at risk (VaR), representing the maximum possible<br />

loss of a portfolio with respect to a given time horizon <strong>an</strong>d a given signific<strong>an</strong>ce level. The<br />

VaR (relative to the distribution’s expected value) c<strong>an</strong> be formally described according to<br />

the following definition.<br />

Definition 6.2 (Value at Risk)<br />

Let (1 − α) be the confidence level for the value at risk with α ∈ (0, 1). Then, the value<br />

at risk of a portfolio’s return is defined by<br />

VaR(x, α) = E[R(x)] − sup {y ∈ R : P[R(x) ≤ y] ≤ α} . (6.2)<br />

In practice, confidence levels of 95% or 99% are usually observed, corresponding to a<br />

level of α of 5% or 1%, respectively. In the c<strong>as</strong>e of a continuous distribution function, the<br />

7 Skewness <strong>an</strong>d kurtosis are defined in equations (5.28 <strong>an</strong>d (5.29)) in Section 5.4.2.<br />

8 See for example [HLLM03].<br />

109


above definition of the VaR c<strong>an</strong> also be rewritten according to<br />

where F −1<br />

R<br />

<strong>an</strong>d<br />

CHAPTER 6. PORTFOLIO SELECTION<br />

VaR(x, α) = E[R(x)] − F −1<br />

R (α), (6.3)<br />

denotes the inverse distribution function of portfolio returns R(x).9<br />

Often, the VaR is me<strong>as</strong>ured relative to zero. Then, equations (6.2) <strong>an</strong>d (6.3) reduce to<br />

VaR0(x, α) = − sup {y ∈ R : P[R(x) ≤ y] ≤ α} , (6.4)<br />

VaR0(x, α) = −F −1<br />

R (α). (6.5)<br />

The VaR <strong>as</strong> risk me<strong>as</strong>ure involves a few problems, such <strong>as</strong> not taking into account the<br />

tail distribution <strong>an</strong>d a lack of subadditivity 10 .<br />

6.2.2 Conditional Value at Risk<br />

The conditional value at risk (CVaR) is a coherent risk me<strong>as</strong>ure, overcoming some defi-<br />

ciencies of the VaR concept. Artzner, Delbaen, Eber, <strong>an</strong>d Heah ([ADEH99]) presented <strong>an</strong><br />

axiomatic approach building the foundation for a coherent risk me<strong>as</strong>ure. 11<br />

The CVaR 12 represents the expected value of all losses that exceed a certain VaR.<br />

Formally, we c<strong>an</strong> define the CVaR according to<br />

Definition 6.3 (Conditional Value at Risk)<br />

Let (1 − α) be the confidence level for the value at risk with α ∈ (0, 1). Then, the condi-<br />

tional value at risk of a portfolio’s return is defined by<br />

CVaR(x, α) = −E[R(x)|R(x) ≤ F −1<br />

R (α)]<br />

= −E[R(x)|R(x) ≤ −VaR0(x, α)]. (6.6)<br />

From the CVaR formul<strong>as</strong> above, it becomes evident that the CVaR provides informa-<br />

tion on the negative tail of a return distribution <strong>as</strong> it is not only focussed on the α-qu<strong>an</strong>tile<br />

9 For more background regarding VaR, we refer for example to [Zag02], pp. 251-253.<br />

10 The me<strong>an</strong>ing of subadditivity will be explained in the next subsection.<br />

11 Let X denote the set of all r<strong>an</strong>dom variables X. Furthermore, a risk me<strong>as</strong>ure is defined <strong>as</strong> me<strong>as</strong>urable<br />

mapping ρ : X → R, <strong>an</strong>d we call ρ(X) the risk of risk position X. Then, a risk me<strong>as</strong>ure is called coherent<br />

if it satisfies axioms 1 - 4.<br />

Axiom 1 [Monotonicity] For all X, Y ∈ X with X ≤ Y<br />

ρ(X) ≥ ρ(Y ).<br />

Axiom 2 [Tr<strong>an</strong>slation-Invari<strong>an</strong>ce] For all X ∈ X <strong>an</strong>d for all c ∈ R we have<br />

ρ(X + c) = ρ(X) − c.<br />

Axiom 3 [Positive Homogenity] For all X ∈ X <strong>an</strong>d for all λ ≥ 0 we have<br />

ρ(λ · X) = λ · ρ(X).<br />

Axiom 3 [Subadditivity] For all X, Y ∈ X we have<br />

ρ(X + Y ) ≤ ρ(X) + ρ(Y ).<br />

(See for example [Zag02], pp. 254-255.)<br />

12 CVaR is also known under the names expected shortfall, worst conditional expectation, tail conditional<br />

expectation, which is for example defined in [Zag02], pp. 262-265.<br />

110


ut also takes into account the shape of its tail.<br />

We formulate the portfolio optimisation problem by<br />

CHAPTER 6. PORTFOLIO SELECTION<br />

min<br />

x<br />

CVaR(x, α) (6.7)<br />

s.t. µ T x ≥ µ<br />

1 T x = 1<br />

x ≥ 0.<br />

Solving the optimisation problem (6.7) for every possible µ, we obtain the set of all<br />

efficient portfolios <strong>an</strong>d the corresponding efficient frontier, which c<strong>an</strong> be displayed in a<br />

µ(x)-CVaR(x, α)-diagram.<br />

6.3 Perform<strong>an</strong>ce Me<strong>as</strong>ure Omega<br />

In this section, we introduce the perform<strong>an</strong>ce me<strong>as</strong>ure Ω, developed by Shadwick <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Keating. 13 It is to overcome the inadequacy of other traditional perform<strong>an</strong>ce me<strong>as</strong>ures 14<br />

when applied to portfolio selection, particularly if returns are not normally distributed.<br />

Unlike other perform<strong>an</strong>ce me<strong>as</strong>ures, such <strong>as</strong> the Sharpe Ratio 15 , it takes into account the<br />

entire return distribution.<br />

Definition 6.4 (Perform<strong>an</strong>ce Me<strong>as</strong>ure Omega)<br />

Let L be a threshold representing the target return, let R = R(x) be the r<strong>an</strong>dom one-period<br />

portfolio return <strong>an</strong>d FR(r) the corresponding cumulative distribution function. Then, Ω is<br />

defined by<br />

Ω(x, L) = Ω(R, L) =<br />

∞�<br />

(1 − FR(r))dr<br />

L<br />

L�<br />

−∞<br />

FR(r)dr<br />

. (6.9)<br />

From the above definition, we observe that the complete return distribution is con-<br />

sidered, <strong>an</strong>d so are higher moments. Furthermore, the threshold L c<strong>an</strong> be determined<br />

individually for every investor. Thus, a better perform<strong>an</strong>ce me<strong>as</strong>urement c<strong>an</strong> be guar<strong>an</strong>-<br />

teed.<br />

∞�<br />

L<br />

The numerator <strong>an</strong>d the denominator in equation (6.9) c<strong>an</strong> be rewritten according to 16<br />

(1 − FR(r))dr =<br />

∞�<br />

L<br />

(r − L)fR(r)dr = E[max(R(x) − L, 0)] =: E[Upside(x)], (6.10)<br />

13 See [SK02].<br />

14 See for example [SB00], pp. 576-585, for more perform<strong>an</strong>ce me<strong>as</strong>ures.<br />

15 The Sharpe Ratio S(R(x)) is defined <strong>as</strong> excess return of a portfolio over the risk-free interest-rate rf ,<br />

relative to the portfolio’s st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation σ:<br />

S(R(x)) =<br />

µ − rf<br />

. (6.8)<br />

σ<br />

It is a sensible perform<strong>an</strong>ce me<strong>as</strong>ure, if <strong>an</strong> investor only h<strong>as</strong> preferences for µ <strong>an</strong>d σ, <strong>as</strong> higher moments<br />

are not taken into account.<br />

16 For the derivation, we refer to [KSG03].<br />

111


L�<br />

−∞<br />

FR(r)dr =<br />

L�<br />

−∞<br />

CHAPTER 6. PORTFOLIO SELECTION<br />

(L − r)fR(r)dr = E[max(L − R(x), 0)] =: E[Downside(x)], (6.11)<br />

where fR(r) is the density function of the one-period portfolio return.<br />

It is obvious that the numerator represents the upside potential of <strong>an</strong> investment, while<br />

the denominator represents the downside potential.<br />

We will apply this perform<strong>an</strong>ce me<strong>as</strong>ure for the portfolio selection with the so-called<br />

score me<strong>as</strong>ure, which will be introduced in the next section.<br />

6.4 Portfolio Selection with Me<strong>as</strong>ure Score<br />

It is our goal to make <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set allocation for two representative investors – one being<br />

risk-averse, <strong>an</strong>d the other being risk-affine. To find <strong>an</strong> optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocation, we need<br />

to consider the risk-aversion of the corresponding investor. An appropriate way to do so,<br />

is the me<strong>as</strong>ure score. 17<br />

Definition 6.5 (Score)<br />

Let E[Upside(x P )], E[Downside(x P )], E[Upside(x B )] <strong>an</strong>d E[Downside(x B )] denote the up-<br />

side potential <strong>an</strong>d the downside (or loss) potential (<strong>as</strong> defined in equations (6.10) <strong>an</strong>d<br />

(6.11), respectively) for a portfolio x P or for a benchmark x B , respectively. λB represents<br />

the risk-aversion of the investor. It is calculated according to<br />

λB = E[Upside(xB )]<br />

E[Downside(xB . (6.12)<br />

)]<br />

Then, the score for a portfolio x P with return R(x P ) is calculated <strong>as</strong><br />

score(x P , λB) = E[Upside(x P )] − λB · E[Downside(x P )]. (6.13)<br />

As we c<strong>an</strong> see from equation (6.12), λB is the same <strong>as</strong> Ω in equation (6.9). Furthermore,<br />

we w<strong>an</strong>t to remark that λB is determined in such a way that the benchmark score is 0.<br />

Note, that the higher λB, the higher the risk-aversion of the investor.<br />

Portfolios c<strong>an</strong> be compared according to their score value – the higher the score, the<br />

better the portfolio. To find <strong>an</strong> optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocation for a given λB, we have to solve<br />

the following optimisation problem:<br />

max<br />

x P<br />

score(x P , λB) (6.14)<br />

s.t. 1 T x P = 1<br />

x P ≥ 0.<br />

For the portfolio selection we chose L := rf <strong>as</strong> the target return to calculate the upside<br />

<strong>an</strong>d downside potential. Before explicitly determining λB, we have a closer look at the<br />

17 See [Zag03].<br />

112


CHAPTER 6. PORTFOLIO SELECTION<br />

upside potential defined in equation (6.10). We c<strong>an</strong> rewrite it according to<br />

∞�<br />

rf<br />

(1 − FR(r))dr =<br />

=<br />

∞�<br />

rf<br />

∞�<br />

−∞<br />

(r − rf )fR(r)dr<br />

(r − rf )fR(r)dr −<br />

= µ(x) − rf +<br />

rf �<br />

−∞<br />

rf �<br />

−∞<br />

(rf − r)fR(r)dr<br />

(r − rf )fR(r)dr<br />

= µ(x) − rf + E[max(rf − R(x), 0)], (6.15)<br />

Now, we w<strong>an</strong>t to determine λB for the benchmark portfolio x B . Plugging equations<br />

(6.11) <strong>an</strong>d (6.15) into equation (6.9), we obtain λB<br />

Ω(x B , rf ) = µ(xB ) − rf + E[max(rf − R(x B ), 0)]<br />

E[max(rf − R(x B ), 0)]<br />

= 1 +<br />

µ(x B ) − rf<br />

E[max(rf − R(x B ), 0)] = λB. (6.16)<br />

From equation (6.16) it becomes obvious that the risk-aversion of <strong>an</strong> investor is me<strong>as</strong>ured<br />

<strong>as</strong> kind of excess return relative to the downside potential. The latter incorporates the<br />

complete portfolio return distribution for returns less th<strong>an</strong> rf .<br />

After having introduced a simulation <strong>an</strong>d pricing framework in Chapter 5, we presented<br />

a few optimisation criteria for portfolio selection in this chapter, which completed the <strong>as</strong>set<br />

allocation framework, so that we are able to apply the <strong>as</strong>set allocation framework, now.<br />

We consider <strong>an</strong> investor in the United States. The corresponding parametrisiation of the<br />

model <strong>an</strong>d the optimisation results are presented in Chapter 7.<br />

113


Chapter 7<br />

Simulation <strong>an</strong>d Simulation Results<br />

After having introduced the tools for simulating <strong>an</strong>d pricing in Chapter 5 <strong>an</strong>d for portfolio<br />

optimisation in Chapter 6, we now present the simulation <strong>an</strong>d optimisation results for <strong>an</strong><br />

investor in the United States. First, we describe the data used for the calibration <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the resulting model parameters. Then, we show the fit of the model interest-rate curve<br />

to the market curve, <strong>as</strong> of 30 th of September, 2006 <strong>an</strong>d we briefly present the parameters<br />

for the simulation of correlated default times. The following subsections are dedicated<br />

to the simulation results. We <strong>an</strong>alyse the single return characteristics of the fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

instruments under consideration (government <strong>an</strong>d corporate (zero-) coupon bonds, <strong>an</strong><br />

equity index, CDS <strong>an</strong>d a CDS index). Thereafter, we present the optimisation results<br />

for the me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce approach, the CVaR optimisation <strong>an</strong>d the score optimisation. In<br />

all c<strong>as</strong>es, we consider different investment universes, different investment horizons <strong>an</strong>d<br />

different investor types. Then, we describe the main observations, applying a higher<br />

default correlation between the reference entities.<br />

7.1 US Economy<br />

7.1.1 Calibration of the Economic Scenario Generator<br />

Model Parameters<br />

To calibrate the ESG, we use parameters estimated by [SZA06] <strong>an</strong>d [Zag06]. We partly<br />

need to adjust them to better meet the updated historical data. They provide parameters<br />

for the GDP growth rate, the short-rate <strong>an</strong>d credit spreads for rating cl<strong>as</strong>ses AA, A2,<br />

BBB1. 1<br />

The short-rate parameters were estimated using non-defaultable weekly bond data (US<br />

Tre<strong>as</strong>ury Strips) 2 from 1 st of October, 1993, until 31 st of December, 2004, with maturities<br />

of 1 year, 2, 3, 4, 5, 7, <strong>an</strong>d 10 years. Figure 7.1 shows the underlying US Tre<strong>as</strong>ury Strips<br />

1 The estimations are done using Kalm<strong>an</strong> filter methodologies. Kalm<strong>an</strong> filters are used if a process is<br />

to be modelled which is not observable in reality. However, if the connection between the unobservable<br />

process <strong>an</strong>d observable data is known, Kalm<strong>an</strong> filter methodologies c<strong>an</strong> be applied. Here, for example,<br />

the short-rate is unobservable, while interest-rates c<strong>an</strong> be observed. This fact is used to estimate the<br />

short-rate parameters. The parameters for the short spread are also estimated that way. The Kalm<strong>an</strong><br />

filter w<strong>as</strong> introduced by R. E. Kalm<strong>an</strong>, see [Kal60].<br />

2 Bloomberg ticker symbols are C0791Y Index, C0792Y Index, C0793Y Index, C0794Y Index, C0795Y<br />

Index, C0797Y Index, C07910Y Index.<br />

114


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

from 1 st of October, 1993, until 30 th of September, 2006. 3<br />

Figure 7.1: US Tre<strong>as</strong>ury Strips<br />

In this figure, we observe a narrowing of interest-rates in recent years. Hence, the US<br />

interest-rate curve is relatively flat. Most of the time, however, the interest-rate curve<br />

implied by US Tre<strong>as</strong>ury Strips h<strong>as</strong> a normal form, i.e. short-term interest-rates are lower<br />

th<strong>an</strong> long-term interest-rates.<br />

In addition to the interest-rate data, quarterly US GDP growth rates were used, ad-<br />

justed by linear interpolation to weekly data. They were incorporated into the estimation<br />

process with a three-quarter time lag. Table 7.1 shows the parameters for the short-rate<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the GDP growth rates.<br />

ar 0.37867<br />

âr 0.24782<br />

br 0.13315<br />

σr 0.0149553<br />

aω 1.18532<br />

âω 0.26847<br />

θω 0.0158331<br />

σω 0.0060146<br />

Table 7.1: Parameter estimation for processes r <strong>an</strong>d ω<br />

The parameters for the rating cl<strong>as</strong>ses AA 4 , A2 5 , BBB1 6 were estimated using average<br />

rates of Americ<strong>an</strong> Industrials for the corresponding rating cl<strong>as</strong>ses on a weekly b<strong>as</strong>is from<br />

3 Note that the estimation period ends at 31 st of December, 2004.<br />

4 Bloomberg ticker symbols for rating cl<strong>as</strong>s AA are C0031Y Index, C0032Y Index, C0033Y Index,<br />

C0034Y Index, C0035Y Index, C0037Y Index, C00310Y Index.<br />

5 Bloomberg ticker symbols for rating cl<strong>as</strong>s A are C0061Y Index, C0062Y Index, C0063Y Index, C0064Y<br />

Index, C0065Y Index, C0067Y Index, C00610Y Index.<br />

6 Bloomberg ticker symbols for rating cl<strong>as</strong>s BBB are C0091Y Index, C0092Y Index, C0093Y Index,<br />

C0094Y Index, C0095Y Index, C0097Y Index, C00910Y Index.<br />

115


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

1 st of October, 1993, until 31 st of December, 2004, with maturities of 1 year, 2, 3, 4, 5, 7,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d 10 years.<br />

The underlying credit spreads are displayed in Figure 7.2. 7<br />

From the sub-figures, we c<strong>an</strong> clearly see a term structure in the credit spreads <strong>an</strong>alogous<br />

to interest-rates. Most of the time, the credit spreads for different maturities have a normal<br />

form, <strong>an</strong>alogous to the observations regarding interest-rate curves.<br />

The high level of the credit spreads in 1998 c<strong>an</strong> be attributed to the Asi<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d Russi<strong>an</strong><br />

crises, while the enormous incre<strong>as</strong>e in 2001 may be attributed to September 11 <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

stock market cr<strong>as</strong>h in the years 2001 <strong>an</strong>d 2002.<br />

The credit spread parameters that we use for the simulations are shown in Table 7.2.<br />

We adjust the estimated parameters âs, âu <strong>an</strong>d bsu to better meet historical data in terms<br />

of average spreads <strong>an</strong>d spread r<strong>an</strong>ges.<br />

AA A2 BBB1<br />

<strong>as</strong> 2.96099 2.80727 2.41739<br />

âs 2.96099 2.80727 2.41739<br />

θs 0.0027474 0.0025139 0.0023778<br />

σs 0.0038855 0.0030875 0.0028679<br />

bsω 0.07373 0.07634 0.09369<br />

au 0.11269 0.11057 0.11048<br />

âu 0.02180 0.03210 0.04075<br />

θu 0.12173 0.18566 0.18980<br />

σu 0.0045920 0.0047604 0.0048862<br />

bsu 0.98404 0.92214 1.26089<br />

Table 7.2: Parameter estimation for processes s <strong>an</strong>d u for rating cl<strong>as</strong>ses AA, A2, BBB1<br />

CDS Index<br />

We <strong>as</strong>sume the US CDS index to be composed of the rating cl<strong>as</strong>ses AA, A, <strong>an</strong>d BBB with<br />

the weights listed in Table 7.3. 8<br />

Equity Index<br />

Rating Weight<br />

AA 12.28%<br />

A 39.47%<br />

BBB 48.25%<br />

Table 7.3: Composition of US CDS index<br />

As we have seen from equation (5.14) the process for the continuous stock returns also<br />

needs <strong>an</strong> inflation process. We use parameters provided by [Zag06]. They are given in<br />

Table 7.4.<br />

7 Note that the estimation period ends at 31 st of December, 2004.<br />

8 See www.fitchratings.com. As we only have parameters for the rating cl<strong>as</strong>ses AA, A, <strong>an</strong>d BBB, we<br />

added the AAA rating cl<strong>as</strong>s to rating cl<strong>as</strong>s AA <strong>an</strong>d BB to BBB. Furthermore, we normalised the weights<br />

to sum up to one.<br />

116


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

ai 0.64073<br />

âi 0.50319<br />

θi 1.0479<br />

σi 0.014470<br />

Table 7.4: Parameter estimation for process i<br />

Regarding the parameters for the equity index, we only adjust the parameters provided<br />

by [Zag06] for the level of the returns <strong>an</strong>d for the st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation to meet updated<br />

historical data of a longer period th<strong>an</strong> the estimation period. The parameters are given<br />

in Table 7.5.<br />

αE 0.00422<br />

bER 3.94000<br />

bEi 5.38436<br />

bEω 5.10643<br />

0.16000<br />

σE<br />

Table 7.5: Parameters for US equity process<br />

117


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.2: US credit spreads, rating cl<strong>as</strong>ses AA, A2, BBB1<br />

118


7.1.2 Fit to Market Data<br />

CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Zero rates at simulation start date (30 th of September, 2006) have to be fitted to market<br />

data. We take US zero rates provided by Bloomberg. 9<br />

We determine the Nelson-Siegel parameters for the log-interest-rate curve. 10 They are<br />

given in Table 7.6.<br />

β0 5.2613%<br />

β1 -0.0130%<br />

β2 -1.3405%<br />

β3 246.7524%<br />

Table 7.6: Nelson-Siegel parameters for US zero rates<br />

The data <strong>an</strong>d the fit of the curve are shown in Figure 7.3.<br />

Figure 7.3: Model fit of US zero rates<br />

7.1.3 Simulation of Correlated Default Times<br />

We simulate correlated default times according to the migration matrices approach, de-<br />

scribed in Section 5.4 with the Gaussi<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d NIG one-factor copula.<br />

For the US economy we use the tr<strong>an</strong>sition matrix provided in Table 5.2. The parame-<br />

ters for the simulation start date are estimated in accord<strong>an</strong>ce with the model introduced<br />

in [KSW05]. In Table 7.7 one c<strong>an</strong> find the parameters of the NIG distribution.<br />

a 0.37029<br />

α 0.70138<br />

β 0<br />

Table 7.7: Parameters of NIG distribution for US economy<br />

9 Bloomberg ticker symbols for US zero rates are F08403M Index, F08401Y Index, F08402Y Index,<br />

F08403Y Index, F08404Y Index, F08405Y Index, F08410Y Index, F08420Y Index, F08430Y Index.<br />

10 See Section 5.3.<br />

119


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Knowing these parameters, the distributions of the factors M, Xi <strong>an</strong>d Ai are uniquely<br />

determined by equations (5.35), (5.36) <strong>an</strong>d (5.38).<br />

To simulate default times with the Gaussi<strong>an</strong> one-factor copula, the only parameter<br />

needed is a, the correlation of a single reference entity to the common market factor 11 . a<br />

is the same <strong>as</strong> in Table 7.7 <strong>as</strong> we simulate default times with the Gaussi<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d NIG one-<br />

factor copula with the same default correlation. The factors M, Xi <strong>an</strong>d Ai are st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

normally distributed <strong>as</strong> we have seen in Section 5.4.2.<br />

The correlation of a single reference entity to the common market factor, a, is equivalent<br />

to a correlation between two reference entities of a 2 = 0.13711, which is rather low. For<br />

this re<strong>as</strong>on, we also perform optimisations for a higher correlation. The results c<strong>an</strong> be<br />

found in Section 7.2.<br />

Having simulated the government interest-rates, the credit spreads <strong>an</strong>d the correlated<br />

default times, we c<strong>an</strong> now price various fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments. The return characteristics<br />

are described in the following section.<br />

7.1.4 Return Characteristics of Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Instruments<br />

The simulation outputs from the ESG <strong>an</strong>d the simulated correlated default times are used<br />

to price the following fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments. We price government coupon <strong>an</strong>d zero-coupon<br />

bonds, corporate coupon <strong>an</strong>d zero-coupon bonds with ratings AA, A, BBB, a CDS index,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d CDS with ratings AA, A, BBB, according to the formul<strong>as</strong> provided in Section 5.5.<br />

All bonds have a maturity of 5 years, while CDS <strong>an</strong>d the CDS index have the maturity<br />

date 20 th of December, 2011, so that they have a maturity of approximately 5.25 years.<br />

Furthermore, we consider <strong>an</strong> equity index, simulated according to equation (5.14) with<br />

the parameters provided in Table 7.5.<br />

We consider the instruments <strong>an</strong>d their return characteristics for investment horizons<br />

of 1 year, 3 years or 5 years. The corresponding key statistics of the fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments<br />

are summarised in Figure 7.4 for Gaussi<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d in Figure 7.5 for NIG default times. 12<br />

Of course, the return characteristics of government bonds are identical for Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

<strong>an</strong>d NIG default times <strong>as</strong> we consider government bonds to be non-defaultable. The return<br />

characteristics of the equity index are also identical for both default times, <strong>as</strong> we simulate<br />

the index return, <strong>as</strong>suming that potential defaults of single stocks are already incorporated<br />

in the index return. Furthermore, the return characteristics for corporate bonds, for CDS<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the CDS index are the same for Gaussi<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d NIG default times, if no defaults have<br />

taken place.<br />

At first, we start with a remark regarding the statistic CVaR in Figures 7.4 <strong>an</strong>d 7.5.<br />

We see that the CVaR values c<strong>an</strong> become negative. This is the c<strong>as</strong>e, if with the me<strong>an</strong> of<br />

11 See Section 5.4.2.<br />

12 The figures contain, for example, the statistic medi<strong>an</strong>, which is defined in the following. Let x1, . . . , xT<br />

denote a r<strong>an</strong>dom sample. The order statistic is given by x(1) ≤ x(2) ≤ . . . ≤ x(T ). Then, the medi<strong>an</strong> is<br />

defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

�<br />

��<br />

medi<strong>an</strong> =<br />

��<br />

x ( T +1<br />

2 )<br />

x ( T 2 ) + x (1+ T 2 )<br />

2<br />

, if T is odd<br />

, if T is even.<br />

Minimum <strong>an</strong>d maximum denote the minimum or the maximum return outcome. The other statistics<br />

are explained in previous chapters.<br />

(7.1)<br />

120


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

the worst 5% of the instrument’s returns does not get negative. 13 In general, the smaller<br />

the CVaR, the less risky is the instrument.<br />

Considering Figures 7.4 <strong>an</strong>d 7.5 we make some general observations. For the one-<br />

year investment horizon the AA-rated CDS, the A-rated CDS <strong>an</strong>d the CDS index have<br />

considerably less volatility <strong>an</strong>d a lower CVaR th<strong>an</strong> government <strong>an</strong>d corporate bonds,<br />

making them relatively save investments. At the same time, CDS <strong>an</strong>d the CDS index<br />

have a similar expected return to government bonds. Therefore, one c<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>sume that<br />

CDS <strong>an</strong>d the CDS index are appropriate instruments to partly replace government <strong>an</strong>d<br />

corporate bonds. This will turn out to be true, <strong>as</strong> shown in the following sections.<br />

Generally, we see higher expected returns <strong>an</strong>d higher st<strong>an</strong>dard deviations or levels<br />

of CVaR with incre<strong>as</strong>ing risk of the instruments. Besides, we observe that – <strong>as</strong> soon<br />

<strong>as</strong> defaults have occurred – the distributions become strongly non-normal. 14 Though,<br />

regarding the tr<strong>an</strong>sition matrix (Table 5.2), it is clear that for 1000 simulations <strong>an</strong>d for a<br />

one-year time horizon, defaults will not take place for every rating cl<strong>as</strong>s. For rating cl<strong>as</strong>s<br />

AA, for example, the one-year probability of default is 0.01%, i.e. statistically, for 1000<br />

simulations 0.1 defaults will occur within one year.<br />

Having a closer look at Figures 7.4 <strong>an</strong>d 7.5, we make a few <strong>as</strong>tonishing observations.<br />

Sometimes the expected return of a lower rating cl<strong>as</strong>s is lower th<strong>an</strong> that of a higher rating<br />

cl<strong>as</strong>s. For example, the expected return of the BBB-rated corporate coupon bond is lower<br />

th<strong>an</strong> for the A-rated corporate coupon bond with NIG default times <strong>an</strong>d a 1 year time<br />

horizon. Regarding the minimum, however, we see that in the simulations of BBB at<br />

le<strong>as</strong>t one default h<strong>as</strong> taken place, while the minimum of A indicates no default. In this<br />

c<strong>as</strong>e, the higher spread for the BBB-rated bond w<strong>as</strong> not able to compensate the number<br />

defaults. The st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation <strong>an</strong>d CVaR behave like expected, they are higher for the<br />

lower rated bond. Moreover, we observe a higher st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation <strong>an</strong>d CVaR-level for<br />

the AA-rated corporate coupon bond th<strong>an</strong> for the A-rated corporate coupon bond with<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times <strong>an</strong>d a 1 year time horizon. Again, regarding the minimum we see<br />

that in the simulations of AA at le<strong>as</strong>t one default h<strong>as</strong> taken place, while the minimum of<br />

A indicates no default. In this c<strong>as</strong>e, the expected returns, however, behave like one would<br />

expect: The me<strong>an</strong> for the higher rated instrument is lower.<br />

Regarding CVaR, particularly for a 1 year investment horizon <strong>an</strong>d high rated bonds,<br />

we see that they partly dominate the government bonds, i.e. the expected return of the<br />

corporate bond is higher th<strong>an</strong> for the government bond, while the CVaR for the corporate<br />

bond is lower. This implies that with CVaR-optimisation hardly <strong>an</strong>y government bonds<br />

will occur in optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocations.<br />

All in all, one have to keep in mind, that we are dealing with simulations, i.e. for<br />

a large number of simulations the results should be stable <strong>an</strong>d should behave, how they<br />

are expected to do. Particularly for default times, however, it is possible, that for a<br />

short time horizon, such <strong>as</strong> 1 year, the simulated number of defaults within this period<br />

is coincidentally higher for a higher rated instrument. Though, for longer time horizons,<br />

such <strong>as</strong> 3 or 5 years the results should be more stable, i.e. the number of default times,<br />

13<br />

As the CVaR is the me<strong>an</strong> of the worst 5% of the portfolio return multiplied by −1, it becomes negative,<br />

if this me<strong>an</strong> is positive.<br />

14<br />

Defaults c<strong>an</strong> be discovered when looking at the minimum returns. If they are smaller th<strong>an</strong>, say, -40%,<br />

we c<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>sume that this is the consequence of a default.<br />

121


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

the me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation should be higher for a low rated instrument th<strong>an</strong> for<br />

<strong>an</strong> instrument with a higher rating because <strong>an</strong> investor bearing a higher risk should be<br />

compensated with a higher expected return. We have already seen this trend in the Figures<br />

7.4 <strong>an</strong>d 7.5.<br />

To obtain a better underst<strong>an</strong>ding of the return characteristics, we show the resulting<br />

densities of the instruments. The empirical distribution function c<strong>an</strong> be calculated by<br />

kernel density estimation, which is a non-parametric method of modelling the univariate<br />

distribution of a r<strong>an</strong>dom variable. 15 The results are given in Figures 7.6, 7.7 <strong>an</strong>d 7.8 for<br />

1 year, <strong>an</strong>d in Figures 7.9, 7.10 <strong>an</strong>d 7.11 for 3 years.<br />

It is not very me<strong>an</strong>ingful to plot the distributions for a 5 years investment horizon for<br />

bonds because all bonds have a maturity of exactly 5 years. Therefore, the zero-coupon<br />

bonds have exactly the same expected returns for every simulated scenario, if no default<br />

h<strong>as</strong> occurred, since both the term structure of interest-rates for the simulation start date<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the payout at maturity are deterministic. Then, all ch<strong>an</strong>ges in interest-rates during<br />

the holding period are irrelev<strong>an</strong>t. As explained, at maturity a zero-coupon bond with<br />

a particular rating h<strong>as</strong> the same expected return for all simulations independent from<br />

the evolution of interest rates, if no defaults have taken place. In the c<strong>as</strong>e of default,<br />

however, the expected return for the corresponding scenario dramatically decre<strong>as</strong>es. This<br />

is the only driver for the st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation of corporate zero-coupon bonds. For coupon<br />

bonds, however, there are little differences between the expected returns after a 5 years<br />

holding period, even if no default h<strong>as</strong> occurred, <strong>as</strong> we <strong>as</strong>sume a reinvestment of the coupon<br />

payment in the considered bond. Then, the total expected return partly depends on the<br />

level of interest-rates at reinvestment dates. This is also why the st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation,<br />

particularly for government bonds, decre<strong>as</strong>es for longer investment horizons: The shorter<br />

the time to maturity, the lower the market risk of bond returns. 16 In contr<strong>as</strong>t to a fixed-<br />

income security, the return of a funded CDS/CDS index is to a large extent driven by the<br />

FRN component, i.e. LIBOR. 17 Hence, it nearly excludes the market risk, <strong>as</strong> the paid<br />

coupon is adjusted to market interest-rates. Coupon payments, however, are <strong>as</strong> volatile <strong>as</strong><br />

interest-rates <strong>an</strong>d therefore volatility incre<strong>as</strong>es for longer investment horizons, i.e. longer<br />

simulation horizons.<br />

In the Figures 7.6 <strong>an</strong>d 7.9 we show the complete distribution of the instruments.<br />

Though, <strong>as</strong> defaults make the density plots too compressed, we additionally plot the tails<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the rest of the distributions in separate Figures (7.7, 7.8, 7.10 <strong>an</strong>d 7.11).<br />

From these figures we c<strong>an</strong> see a non-normality of the distributions if defaults have<br />

taken place. Moreover, we see again that for the one-year investment horizon the AA-<br />

rated CDS, the A-rated CDS <strong>an</strong>d the CDS index have considerably less volatility th<strong>an</strong><br />

government <strong>an</strong>d corporate bonds, while having a similar expected return to government<br />

bonds. 18<br />

In Figure 7.12, we show the linear correlations 19 between the returns of the fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

15<br />

For more background regarding kernel density estimation we refer for example to [Har95], pp. 840-844.<br />

The figures were made by using the MATLAB function ksdensity with its default parameters.<br />

16<br />

The market risk of bonds is explained in Section 2.2.<br />

17<br />

The return components of a funded CDS <strong>an</strong>d of a funded CDS index are described in Sections 5.5.5<br />

<strong>an</strong>d 5.5.6.<br />

18<br />

The same observation we already made in the Figures 7.4 <strong>an</strong>d 7.5.<br />

19<br />

For a definition of the linear correlation, see equation (5.9).<br />

122


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

instruments for the investment horizons 1 year, 3 years <strong>an</strong>d 5 years. This matrices are one<br />

of the inputs for the me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimisation conducted in Section 7.1.5.<br />

Regarding the correlation matrices, we make the following main observations.<br />

• Bond returns have a high positive correlation for a 1 year <strong>an</strong>d 3 years investment<br />

horizon. This is re<strong>as</strong>onable <strong>as</strong> the main driver of the bond return is the government<br />

rate, which is the same for all bonds. Differences in bond returns come form different<br />

credit spreads <strong>an</strong>d different default times.<br />

• Bond <strong>an</strong>d equity index returns are negatively correlated for a 1 year <strong>an</strong>d 3 years<br />

investment horizon. A negative correlation between bond <strong>an</strong>d stock returns c<strong>an</strong> also<br />

be empirically observed. This phenomenon c<strong>an</strong> be explained <strong>as</strong> follows. In times<br />

of low interest rates, i.e. low bond returns, comp<strong>an</strong>ies strongly invest, resulting in<br />

higher profits of the comp<strong>an</strong>ies <strong>an</strong>d therefore higher equity returns.<br />

• There is a small positive or negative correlation between returns of bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS<br />

or the CDS index for a 1 year <strong>an</strong>d 3 years investment horizon. We c<strong>an</strong> explain the<br />

low correlation between bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS <strong>as</strong> follows. The bonds are fixed income<br />

instruments, whose price strongly depends on the level of interest rates: If interest<br />

rates are falling, the bond returns incre<strong>as</strong>e <strong>as</strong> bond prices incre<strong>as</strong>e. For CDS <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the CDS index its the other way round, since their return strongly depends on the<br />

floating rate LIBOR <strong>an</strong>d to a smaller part on other components, such <strong>as</strong> the fixed<br />

spread. 20 Therefore, returns of CDS <strong>an</strong>d CDS indices tend to decre<strong>as</strong>e with falling<br />

interest rates.<br />

• The returns of the equity index <strong>an</strong>d CDS or CDS index are positively correlated.<br />

This is re<strong>as</strong>onable since both equity returns <strong>an</strong>d the 3 month government rate are<br />

to a large proportion driven by the short-rate. 21<br />

The correlation for the five years investment horizon is not that me<strong>an</strong>ingful for similar<br />

re<strong>as</strong>ons <strong>as</strong> explained earlier in this section.<br />

To conclude, due to appealing risk-return-profiles <strong>an</strong>d low correlations between bonds,<br />

the equity index <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS index, investors should benefit from holding a portfolio<br />

consisting of several fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments. This is examined in the following sections.<br />

20<br />

For more information regarding the return components of funded CDS <strong>an</strong>d funded CDS indices we<br />

refer to Sections 5.5.5 <strong>an</strong>d 5.5.6.<br />

21<br />

See equation (5.14) for the dynamics of the equity index <strong>an</strong>d equation (5.19) for the calculation of the<br />

zero rate.<br />

123


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.4: Key statistics US economy, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults<br />

124


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.5: Key statistics US economy, NIG defaults<br />

125


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.6: Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 1 year time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults<br />

(left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

126


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.7: Left tail densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 1 year time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

Figure 7.8: Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments without left tails, 1 year time horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

127


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.9: Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 3 years time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults<br />

(left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

128


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.10: Left tail densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 3 years time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

Figure 7.11: Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments without left tails, 3 years time horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

129


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.12: Correlation of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments in US economy, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults <strong>an</strong>d<br />

NIG defaults<br />

130


7.1.5 Me<strong>an</strong>-Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Approach<br />

CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Before presenting the optimisation results, we w<strong>an</strong>t to repeat that we aim at finding<br />

the efficient frontiers for different investment universes described in Remark 7.1 <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

corresponding <strong>as</strong>set allocations for every point on the efficient frontiers. We consider three<br />

different investment horizons, 1 year, 3 years <strong>an</strong>d 5 years.<br />

Remark 7.1<br />

The optimisation is conducted for the following three investment universes.<br />

(a) We <strong>as</strong>sume <strong>an</strong> initial investment universe consisting of government bonds <strong>an</strong>d stocks.<br />

(b) Then, we add corporate bonds to the investment universe.<br />

(c) Finally, we consider the efficient frontier <strong>an</strong>d the respective <strong>as</strong>set allocations, also<br />

allowing for a CDS index <strong>an</strong>d CDS.<br />

Conducting a me<strong>an</strong> vari<strong>an</strong>ce-optimisation according to the optimisation problem (6.1)<br />

<strong>an</strong>d following the steps listed in Remark 7.1, we obtain the results displayed in Figures<br />

7.14, 7.15 <strong>an</strong>d 7.16.<br />

These figures are built up in a similar way. On the left-h<strong>an</strong>d side we find the results<br />

for pricing with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times, while on the right-h<strong>an</strong>d side we see the results<br />

with NIG default times. The sub-figures on top show the efficient frontiers for the three<br />

investment universes described in Remark 7.1. The following sub-figures show the optimal<br />

<strong>as</strong>set allocations in each respective universe, for all resulting levels of risk. Note that for<br />

re<strong>as</strong>ons of readability we display the weights of the bonds with the same rating cl<strong>as</strong>s in<br />

one colour, i. e. we add their weights <strong>an</strong>d display the sum, for example, we add the weight<br />

of the zero-coupon bond <strong>an</strong>d the coupon bond rated A in the optimal allocation <strong>an</strong>d show<br />

the sum in a light grey. Analogously, we display the weights of all CDS in one colour. We<br />

plot the optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocations for all three investment universes <strong>an</strong>d for all investment<br />

horizons.<br />

As already explained in Section 7.1.4, we do not consider defaults for government bonds<br />

<strong>an</strong>d for equity indices. Therefore, the results are the same for both default times.<br />

For investors optimising their portfolios according to the me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce criterium, we<br />

c<strong>an</strong> identify some general structures.<br />

At first, we examine the efficient frontiers 22 :<br />

• Allowing for corporate bonds in the portfolio optimisation leads to <strong>an</strong> upward shift<br />

of the efficient frontier compared to a portfolio only consisting of government bonds<br />

<strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> equity index: For the same level of risk, a higher expected return c<strong>an</strong> be<br />

generated.<br />

• Allowing additionally for CDS <strong>an</strong>d a CDS index in the portfolio optimisation leads<br />

to a shift to the left of the efficient frontier, compared to a portfolio consisting of<br />

government bonds, corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> equity index, i.e. the portfolio risk c<strong>an</strong><br />

be reduced. The proportion of the potential risk reduction, however, depends on the<br />

investment horizon:<br />

22 For more background regarding efficient frontiers, we refer to Section 6.1.1<br />

131


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

– For a 1 year horizon, <strong>an</strong> enormous risk reduction c<strong>an</strong> be achieved. The minimum-<br />

vari<strong>an</strong>ce portfolio 23 consisting of government bonds <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> equity index h<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong><br />

expected return of 6.16% <strong>an</strong>d a st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation of 3.12%, while the port-<br />

folio allowing for all instruments, which h<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> expected return of 6.16%, h<strong>as</strong><br />

a st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation of only 0.76% for Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times <strong>an</strong>d 0.91% for<br />

NIG default times.<br />

– For a 3 years investment horizon, a slight risk reduction c<strong>an</strong> be achieved by<br />

adding CDS <strong>an</strong>d CDS indices. Considering a 5 years investment horizon, the<br />

benefit of adding CDS is marginal.<br />

This shift of the efficient frontier by allowing for corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS index<br />

c<strong>an</strong> be attributed to a low correlation between these <strong>as</strong>sets <strong>an</strong>d to the appealing risk-return<br />

profile of these instruments. 24<br />

Then, we consider the me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocations:<br />

• In <strong>an</strong> efficient <strong>as</strong>set allocation, government bonds are totally or partially substituted<br />

with corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS index. The re<strong>as</strong>on for that is also the low<br />

correlation <strong>an</strong>d the attractive risk-return profile for corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS<br />

index compared to government bonds, particularly for the 1 year investment horizon.<br />

As we have seen from Figures 7.4 <strong>an</strong>d 7.5, CDS have a similar expected return to<br />

government bonds but a much lower st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation for a 1 year horizon. The<br />

phenomenon of decre<strong>as</strong>ing volatility of bonds <strong>an</strong>d incre<strong>as</strong>ing volatility of CDS/CDS<br />

index over time w<strong>as</strong> already explained in Section 7.1.4. Particularly for low levels of<br />

risk, corporate bonds are replaced by CDS/CDS index.<br />

– For levels of st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation higher th<strong>an</strong> 5.77% (Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default time)<br />

<strong>an</strong>d 5.54% (NIG) <strong>an</strong> optimal portfolio only consists of corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong><br />

equity index for a 1 year horizon.<br />

– For lower levels of st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation, corporate bonds are partially replaced<br />

by CDS/CDS index, which reach a level of 90% in <strong>an</strong> optimal allocation with<br />

a st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation of approximately 0.5%. There is only a very small pro-<br />

portion of government bonds for a very low level of risk, due to the risk-return<br />

profile of government bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS.<br />

– For a 3 years time horizon we see a similar picture: For low levels of st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

deviation, corporate bonds are partially substituted by CDS/CDS index, reach-<br />

ing a level of nearly 50%. Now, government bonds are again used in <strong>an</strong> optimal<br />

allocation, due to a similar risk-return profile to CDS.<br />

– For a 5 years horizon, we hardly see <strong>an</strong>y CDS. Now, we observe a large pro-<br />

portion of government bonds for low levels of risk. The re<strong>as</strong>on is that govern-<br />

ment bonds have a very low st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation, <strong>as</strong> they have a maturity of<br />

5 years. Therefore, the payments are received without <strong>an</strong>y uncertainties <strong>an</strong>d<br />

without reinvestment risk in the c<strong>as</strong>e of zero-coupon bonds, while the st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

23 For <strong>an</strong> expl<strong>an</strong>ation of the minimum-vari<strong>an</strong>ce portfolio we refer to Section 6.1.1.<br />

24 See Figures 7.12, 7.4 <strong>an</strong>d 7.5, respectively.<br />

132


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

deviation of CDS/CDS index continuously incre<strong>as</strong>es with a longer investment<br />

horizon.<br />

• Comparing the allocations of instruments with the same rating cl<strong>as</strong>s, but priced with<br />

different default times, we make the following observations, which c<strong>an</strong> be attributed<br />

to the risk-return profile of these instruments:<br />

– For a 1 year <strong>an</strong>d 3 years investment horizon, instruments which are priced<br />

using Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times allocate a larger proportion in A-rated corporate<br />

bonds, while a pricing with NIG default times leads to a larger proportion<br />

allocated in BBB-rated corporate bonds. BBB-rated coupon bonds within<br />

NIG default times are more attractive compared to their counterparts within<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times. In contr<strong>as</strong>t, we make the reverse observation for A-<br />

rated bonds. 25 The allocation in CDS/CDS index is similar.<br />

– For a 5 years horizon we see a reverse trend. A larger proportion is allocated<br />

in BBB-rated corporate bonds with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times. Comparing the<br />

risk-return profiles of these bonds for Gaussi<strong>an</strong> with NIG default times, we now<br />

see the opposite of what w<strong>as</strong> described for the 1 year horizon.<br />

Figure 7.13 shows the potential return enh<strong>an</strong>cement for the minimum-vari<strong>an</strong>ce port-<br />

folio in the investment universe only allowing for government bonds <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> equity index.<br />

The return enh<strong>an</strong>cements are shown for optimal portfolios with the same level of risk<br />

<strong>as</strong> the minimum-vari<strong>an</strong>ce portfolio, now, however, allowing for other credit risk bearing<br />

instruments. These portfolios are displayed for the investment horizons of 1 year <strong>an</strong>d 3<br />

years, <strong>an</strong>d both default times.<br />

It is not re<strong>as</strong>onable to show the table for the 5 year investment horizon, because the<br />

lowest st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation is zero in the c<strong>as</strong>e of a government zero-coupon bond. Therefore,<br />

no return improvement is possible for the same level of risk by adding other instruments.<br />

The first line always shows the minimum-vari<strong>an</strong>ce portfolio in the investment universe<br />

only allowing for government bonds <strong>an</strong>d stocks. For the horizons of 1 year <strong>an</strong>d 3 years, we<br />

see that there are at most marginal differences when additionally allowing for corporate<br />

bonds, because the portfolio with the lowest st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation normally only consists of<br />

government bonds <strong>an</strong>d stocks. On the contrary, there is <strong>an</strong> enormous improvement of the<br />

expected portfolio return, when the investment universe is extended by CDS/CDS index<br />

for re<strong>as</strong>ons explained earlier.<br />

From the <strong>an</strong>alyses above, we c<strong>an</strong> draw the following conclusions. An investor applying<br />

the me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce criterium for portfolio selection c<strong>an</strong> add perform<strong>an</strong>ce to his portfolio for<br />

a given level of risk, or he c<strong>an</strong> reduce risk for a target return level. This c<strong>an</strong> be achieved due<br />

to the low correlation <strong>an</strong>d the risk-return profile of the instruments by partially replacing<br />

his government bond investment by a combination of corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS<br />

index.<br />

25 Furthermore, the st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation of the BBB-rated coupon bond is lower th<strong>an</strong> that of the A-rated<br />

coupon bond for NIG default times, <strong>as</strong> already explained in Section 7.1.4.<br />

133


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.13: Minimum-vari<strong>an</strong>ce portfolio with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d<br />

NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

134


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.14: Results of me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimisation, 1 year investment horizon with<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

135


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.15: Results of me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimisation, 3 years investment horizon with<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

136


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.16: Results of me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimisation, 5 years investment horizon with<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

137


7.1.6 Conditional Value at Risk<br />

CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Now, we present the results of the CVaR-optimisation according to the optimisation prob-<br />

lem (6.7) with the investment universes listed in Remark 7.1. α is <strong>as</strong>sumed to be = 5%,<br />

i.e. we consider the me<strong>an</strong> of the worst 5% of the portfolio return <strong>as</strong> risk me<strong>as</strong>ure. 26<br />

The results are displayed in Figures 7.18, 7.19 <strong>an</strong>d 7.20, which are built up in <strong>an</strong>alogy<br />

to the figures in Section 7.1.5.<br />

The first striking observation is that the CVaR values c<strong>an</strong> become negative because<br />

there are portfolios with a me<strong>an</strong> of the worst 5% of the portfolio returns that does not<br />

become negative. 27 In general, the smaller the CVaR, the less risky is the portfolio.<br />

Comparing the results of the CVaR optimisation with the results of the me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

optimisation, the first impression is very similar. In the following, we present the main<br />

results from the CVaR optimisation.<br />

We begin considering the efficient frontiers:<br />

• Adding corporate bonds to a portfolio consisting of government bonds <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> equity<br />

index leads to <strong>an</strong> upward shift of the efficient frontier, compared to a portfolio only<br />

consisting of government bonds <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> equity index: For the same level of CVaR, a<br />

higher expected return c<strong>an</strong> be generated.<br />

• Adding CDS <strong>an</strong>d a CDS index to the portfolio of government bonds, corporate bonds<br />

<strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> equity index, <strong>an</strong> enormous risk reduction c<strong>an</strong> be achieved for a 1 year horizon.<br />

The minimum-CVaR portfolio consisting of government bonds <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> equity index<br />

h<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> expected return of 6.55% <strong>an</strong>d a CVaR of 0.25%, while the portfolio allowing<br />

for all instruments, which h<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> expected return of 6.55%, h<strong>as</strong> a CVaR of only<br />

-3.81% for Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times, <strong>an</strong>d -3.59% for NIG default times.<br />

• For a 3 years investment horizon, a slight incre<strong>as</strong>e of the efficient frontier c<strong>an</strong> be<br />

reached by adding CDS/CDS index.<br />

• Considering a 5 years investment horizon, there is no benefit of adding CDS/CDS<br />

index to a portfolio.<br />

The observed shift of the efficient frontier by allowing for corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS<br />

index c<strong>an</strong> be attributed to several facts: A low correlation between these <strong>as</strong>sets, imply-<br />

ing diversification effects <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> attractive risk-return profile of the credit risk bearing<br />

instruments. 28<br />

Then, we regard the optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocations for <strong>an</strong> investor using the CVaR-criterium:<br />

• In <strong>an</strong> efficient <strong>as</strong>set allocation, government bonds are totally or partially substituted<br />

with corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS index. The re<strong>as</strong>on for that is the low correla-<br />

tion <strong>an</strong>d the attractive risk-return profile of corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS index<br />

compared to government bonds, particularly for the 1 year investment horizon. As<br />

26 For more background see Section 6.2.<br />

27 As the CVaR is the me<strong>an</strong> of the worst 5% of the portfolio return multiplied by −1, it becomes negative,<br />

if this me<strong>an</strong> is positive.<br />

28 See Figures 7.12, 7.4 <strong>an</strong>d 7.5.<br />

138


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

we have seen from Figures 7.4 <strong>an</strong>d 7.5, CDS have a similar expected return to gov-<br />

ernment bonds, but a lower CVaR for a 1 year horizon. Particularly for low levels<br />

of risk, corporate bonds are replaced by CDS/CDS index.<br />

– For levels of CVaR higher th<strong>an</strong> 4.8% (Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default time) <strong>an</strong>d 5.0% (NIG)<br />

<strong>an</strong> optimal portfolio only consists of corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> equity index for a<br />

1 year horizon.<br />

– For lower levels of CVaR, corporate bonds are partially replaced by CDS/CDS<br />

index, which reach a level of approximately 90% in <strong>an</strong> optimal allocation with<br />

a CVaR of approximately 4.7%. There are no government bonds in the optimal<br />

allocation, due to the risk-return profile of the instruments.<br />

– For a 3 years time horizon we see a similar picture: For low levels of CVaR,<br />

corporate bonds are partially substituted by CDS/CDS index, reaching a level<br />

of at le<strong>as</strong>t 40%. Now, government bonds are used in <strong>an</strong> optimal allocation<br />

applying Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times, due to the risk-return profile.<br />

• We compare the allocations resulting from Gaussi<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d NIG default times. The<br />

observed effects c<strong>an</strong> be explained with the risk-return profiles of the instruments: 29<br />

– For a 1 <strong>an</strong>d 3 years investment horizon, instruments, which are priced using<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times, allocate a larger proportion in A-rated corporate bonds,<br />

while a pricing with NIG default times leads to a larger proportion allocated in<br />

BBB-rated corporate bonds. The allocation in CDS/CDS index is similar.<br />

– For a 5 years horizon, the efficient portfolios priced with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times<br />

partly contain a considerable proportion of government bonds. Efficient portfo-<br />

lios priced with NIG default times contain more A-rated corporate bonds, since<br />

these bonds dominate government bonds.<br />

Figure 7.17 is equivalent to Figure 7.13. 30 We see that there is <strong>an</strong> enormous improve-<br />

ment of the expected portfolio return when additionally allowing for corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d<br />

CDS/CDS index due to diversification effects.<br />

Our <strong>an</strong>alyses showed that <strong>an</strong> investor, optimising his portfolio with the CVaR cri-<br />

terium, c<strong>an</strong> add perform<strong>an</strong>ce to his portfolio for a given level of risk, or he c<strong>an</strong> reduce risk<br />

for a target return level. This c<strong>an</strong> be achieved by partially substituting government bonds<br />

with corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS index.<br />

29 See Figures 7.4 <strong>an</strong>d 7.5.<br />

30 For a description, we refer to Section 7.1.7.<br />

139


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.17: Minimum-CVaR portfolio with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG<br />

defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

140


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.18: Results of CVaR optimisation, 1 year investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

141


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.19: Results of CVaR optimisation, 3 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

142


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.20: Results of CVaR optimisation, 5 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

143


7.1.7 Score<br />

CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

In this subsection, we describe the results of the score optimisation, which is conducted<br />

according to optimisation problem (6.14).<br />

We examine the optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocation for two representative investors – a risk-averse<br />

<strong>an</strong>d a risk-affine investor. The composition of the investor’s benchmark portfolio is given<br />

in Table 7.8.<br />

<strong>Asset</strong> Cl<strong>as</strong>s Risk-Averse Investor Risk-Affine Investor<br />

Government Bonds 70% 30%<br />

Equity Index 30% 70%<br />

Table 7.8: Characterisation of representative investors<br />

This <strong>an</strong>alysis is done for the investment universes listed in Remark 7.1 for a 1 year, a<br />

3 <strong>an</strong>d a 5 years investment horizon.<br />

Some statistics <strong>an</strong>d the results of the optimisation are shown in Figures 7.21, 7.22<br />

<strong>an</strong>d 7.23. The top sub-figures show the results for the investment universe without CDS<br />

<strong>an</strong>d CDS index, while the bottom sub-figures show the results for the complete investment<br />

universe. The statistics are displayed in a light grey, in the first part of the sub-figures. The<br />

statistic ”risk” denotes Ω <strong>as</strong> defined in equation (6.9) 31 , the score value is maximised by<br />

the optimisation. A positive score value indicates that, for a certain investor, the portfolio<br />

is better th<strong>an</strong> the benchmark portfolio. The optimal allocations c<strong>an</strong> be found in the<br />

second part of the sub-figures. Analogous to the previous sections, we sum up the weights<br />

of coupon bonds <strong>an</strong>d zero-coupon bonds with the same credit quality. Additionally, we<br />

sum up the weights of the CDS. <strong>Asset</strong>s with a proportion higher th<strong>an</strong> 30% are printed<br />

in bold letters. As before, the results for the Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times c<strong>an</strong> be found on<br />

the left-h<strong>an</strong>d side, results for the NIG default times on the right-h<strong>an</strong>d side. Within a<br />

sub-figure, we present the outcomes for the risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d the risk-affine investor.<br />

Before <strong>an</strong>alysing the results of the score optimisation, we make a few remarks regarding<br />

this optimisation procedure. The score value of a portfolio is calculated <strong>as</strong> expected upside<br />

potential, less the expected downside potential, which is weighted with λB, the investor’s<br />

risk-aversion. 32 Hence, the optimisation is done, searching for the best tradeoff between<br />

upside <strong>an</strong>d downside potential, taking into account the investor’s risk-aversion. Applying<br />

this optimisation procedure, the complete return distribution of the portfolios is consid-<br />

ered, i.e. particularly heavy tails of single <strong>as</strong>sets which are implied by defaults. 33 Note<br />

that the higher the upside potential of <strong>an</strong> instrument, the higher the downside potential,<br />

such <strong>as</strong> for equity indices. In the score optimisation the downside potential is multiplied<br />

by λB, which is usually considerably higher th<strong>an</strong> 1. 34 Therefore, the downside potential<br />

h<strong>as</strong> a higher weight th<strong>an</strong> the upside potential when determining the score. Consequently,<br />

the proportion of rather risky <strong>as</strong>sets will be limited, in order to obtain a positive score.<br />

For this re<strong>as</strong>on, it will turn out in our optimisations, that the proportion of the equity<br />

index in <strong>an</strong> optimal portfolio is at most 36.3%, even for the risk-affine investor.<br />

31 The higher Ω, the better.<br />

32 See Section 6.4.<br />

33 See Section 7.1.4 for distributional properties.<br />

34 See Figures 7.21, 7.22 <strong>an</strong>d 7.23.<br />

144


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

The following observations c<strong>an</strong> all be attributed to a few facts: first, to the character-<br />

istics of the optimisation procedure <strong>as</strong> explained earlier; second to the risk-return profiles<br />

shown in Figures 7.4 <strong>an</strong>d 7.5; third to the diversification effects implied by low correlations<br />

between the instruments shown in Figure 7.12.<br />

Figure 7.21: Results of score optimisation, 1 year investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

For every investment horizon, we c<strong>an</strong> observe that λB is higher for the risk-averse<br />

investor th<strong>an</strong> for the risk-affine. This confirms what w<strong>as</strong> already stated in Section 6.4:<br />

The higher the risk-aversion, the higher λB.<br />

At first, we consider the 1 year investment horizon. We begin with general observations.<br />

Then, we have a closer look at the different types of investors.<br />

• For both default times, we see that both investor types have a lower proportion of<br />

the equity index compared to the initial allocation (see Table 7.8). The optimal<br />

allocation never contains government bonds.<br />

• Comparing the level of the benchmark <strong>an</strong>d the expected portfolio return, we see that<br />

for risk-affine investors the expected portfolio return is smaller th<strong>an</strong> the benchmark<br />

return. Regarding the risk-averse investors, we c<strong>an</strong>not observe a clear trend.<br />

• With Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times, a risk-averse investor should allocate approximately<br />

18% into CDS.<br />

• With NIG default times, a risk-averse investor does not invest into CDS.<br />

• A risk-affine investor never h<strong>as</strong> CDS in his portfolio.<br />

145


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.22: Results of score optimisation, 3 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

• For NIG default times the optimal portfolio consists of only 2 <strong>as</strong>sets, the equity<br />

index <strong>an</strong>d BBB-rated corporate bonds.<br />

• Comparing Gaussi<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d NIG default times, we observe that optimal allocations<br />

have a higher proportion of the equity index <strong>an</strong>d a much higher proportion of BBB-<br />

rated corporate bonds for NIG default times, while applying Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times<br />

leads to a considerable proportion of A-rated corporate bonds.<br />

Next, we consider the 3 <strong>an</strong>d the 5 years investment horizon.<br />

• Now, all resulting allocations have a lower expected portfolio return th<strong>an</strong> their bench-<br />

mark. The risk-averse investor’s portfolio, however, h<strong>as</strong> similar expected returns <strong>as</strong><br />

the benchmark.<br />

• For the 3 years horizon, the portfolios never contain government bonds. For a 5<br />

years investment horizon, the optimal portfolio determined with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default<br />

times also allocates into government bonds.<br />

• Optimising with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> or NIG default times entails different allocations, but<br />

similar resulting expected returns. The allocation into CDS differs somewhat. A<br />

risk-averse investor with a 3 years investment horizon should have a CDS proportion<br />

of 1.27% (Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default time) or 0.37% (NIG default time) in his portfolio. A risk-<br />

averse investor with a 5 years time horizon should have 8.67% CDS with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

146


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.23: Results of score optimisation, 5 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

default times <strong>an</strong>d no CDS with NIG default times. A risk-affine investor does not<br />

have CDS in his portfolio.<br />

Our <strong>an</strong>alyses showed that <strong>an</strong> investor optimising his portfolio with the score me<strong>as</strong>ure<br />

c<strong>an</strong> obtain a better risk-return profile compared to his benchmark portfolio only consisting<br />

of government bonds <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> equity index. This c<strong>an</strong> be achieved by partially substituting<br />

government bonds <strong>an</strong>d the equity index with corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS index.<br />

147


7.1.8 Comparison of Optimal Portfolios<br />

CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

We close this section of the simulation results for the US economy with a comparison of<br />

the optimal portfolios. The optimal allocations are shown for a risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d a risk-affine<br />

investor having a benchmark portfolio <strong>as</strong> listed in Table 7.8. For the investment universe<br />

allowing for all instruments, i.e. government <strong>an</strong>d corporate bonds, CDS/CDS index <strong>an</strong>d<br />

<strong>an</strong> equity index, we display the optimal portfolios with the same st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation <strong>an</strong>d<br />

CVaR, respectively, <strong>as</strong> the benchmark portfolio, <strong>as</strong> well <strong>as</strong> the corresponding optimal<br />

portfolio according to score optimisation. The data for the me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d CVaR-<br />

optimal portfolios is taken from the optimisation output presented in Sections 7.1.5 <strong>an</strong>d<br />

7.1.6. The data for the score optimisation c<strong>an</strong> be found in Section 7.1.7. ”Risk” denotes<br />

the corresponding risk me<strong>as</strong>ure used for the optimisation, i.e. the st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation,<br />

CVaR or Ω. The results are shown in the following figures.<br />

Figure 7.24: Results for risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d risk-affine investor, 1 year investment horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (top) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (bottom)<br />

Beginning with general observations, we see similar resulting expected portfolio returns<br />

<strong>an</strong>d portfolio allocations for me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d CVaR optimisation. Having a closer look<br />

at the results, we see that the resulting expected portfolio returns from CVaR optimisation<br />

are higher th<strong>an</strong> for the other optimisation procedures. The highest proportion of the equity<br />

index c<strong>an</strong> also be observed with the CVaR optimisation. The equity index proportion for<br />

me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimisation is not subst<strong>an</strong>tially lower th<strong>an</strong> with CVaR. In contr<strong>as</strong>t, the<br />

score optimisation always leads to a considerably lower proportion of the equity index. 35<br />

CVaR <strong>an</strong>d me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimisation never allocate in government bonds for the two<br />

types of investors. This c<strong>an</strong> be attributed to the risk-return profile of the instruments. 36<br />

For the 1 year horizon, the optimisation according to the CVaR criterium leads to a<br />

35 The only exception is the result for the 1 year horizon, Ω-optimisation, risk-averse investor.<br />

36 See Figures 7.4 <strong>an</strong>d 7.5 for the key statistics of the fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments under consideration. For a<br />

detailed discussion of the resulting optimal allocations, we refer to Sections 7.1.5, 7.1.6 <strong>an</strong>d 7.1.7.<br />

148


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.25: Results for risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d risk-affine investor, 3 years investment horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (top) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (bottom)<br />

subst<strong>an</strong>tial proportion of CDS for both default times. The re<strong>as</strong>on for that is the very<br />

attractive risk-return profile of CDS/CDS index in the low-risk field compared to bonds.<br />

For other time horizons, there are at most small proportions of CDS/CDS index,<br />

because they are primarily attractive for very low levels of risk. Optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocations,<br />

however, always contain a considerable proportion of corporate bonds.<br />

To conclude, comparing the resulting optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocations for a representative risk-<br />

averse <strong>an</strong>d risk-affine investor, we see that independent from investment horizon <strong>an</strong>d from<br />

optimisation criterium <strong>an</strong> investor always benefits from substituting government bonds by<br />

corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS index.<br />

149


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.26: Results for risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d risk-affine investor, 5 years investment horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (top) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (bottom)<br />

150


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

7.2 US Economy with Higher Default Correlation<br />

In the previous subsections, the correlation between the reference entities is <strong>as</strong>sumed to<br />

be a 2 = 0.13711, which is rather low. To examine the effects of a higher correlation,<br />

we conduct the same return calculations <strong>an</strong>d optimisations <strong>as</strong> in Section 7.1, but now<br />

applying a default correlation of 0.3. 37 The results are presented in the following. In this<br />

section, we mainly concentrate on describing the main observations <strong>an</strong>d the differences in<br />

the simulation results between the actual <strong>an</strong>d the higher default correlation.<br />

7.2.1 Return Characteristics<br />

Figures 7.27 <strong>an</strong>d 7.28 show the key statistics of all fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments under considera-<br />

tion for Gaussi<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d NIG default times.<br />

From Figures 7.27 <strong>an</strong>d 7.28 we make some general observations. For the one-year in-<br />

vestment horizon the CDS <strong>an</strong>d the CDS index have considerably less volatility <strong>an</strong>d a lower<br />

CVaR th<strong>an</strong> government <strong>an</strong>d corporate bonds, making them relatively save investments.<br />

At the same time, CDS <strong>an</strong>d the CDS index have a similar expected return to govern-<br />

ment bonds. Therefore, one c<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>sume that CDS <strong>an</strong>d the CDS index are appropriate<br />

instruments to partly replace government <strong>an</strong>d corporate bonds. Generally, we see higher<br />

expected returns <strong>an</strong>d higher st<strong>an</strong>dard deviations or levels of CVaR with incre<strong>as</strong>ing risk of<br />

the instruments.<br />

Having a closer look at the statistic CVaR, particularly for a 1 year investment horizon<br />

<strong>an</strong>d high rated bonds, we see that they partly dominate the government bonds, i.e. the<br />

expected return of the corporate bond is higher th<strong>an</strong> for the government bond, while the<br />

CVaR for the corporate bond is lower. 38 This implies that with CVaR-optimisation hardly<br />

<strong>an</strong>y government bonds will occur in optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocations.<br />

We c<strong>an</strong> observe a clear tendency which c<strong>an</strong>not be observed for the low default correla-<br />

tion: The lower the credit quality, the more non-normal the return distribution of single<br />

instruments priced with NIG default time compared to pricing with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default time.<br />

This becomes obvious considering the skewness <strong>an</strong>d excess kurtosis, because both statis-<br />

tics indicate a non-normality, which is the stronger, the bigger the deviation from zero.<br />

This is the result of what we already have seen in Figure 5.5: The lower the credit rating<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the higher the default correlation, the more pairwise defaults occur within a short<br />

investment horizon.<br />

Comparing the statistics with high default correlation to those with the actual default<br />

correlation, we also see that within one default time, i.e. only considering the Gaussi<strong>an</strong> or<br />

NIG default time, the return distributions are more non-normal with default correlation<br />

of 0.3. 39 Again, this becomes obvious considering the skewness <strong>an</strong>d excess kurtosis. We<br />

also c<strong>an</strong> explain this observation with the observations we have made in Figure 5.5: For a<br />

certain rating cl<strong>as</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d a certain one-factor copula, the joint defaults are the higher, the<br />

higher default correlation is.<br />

37 For a detailed description of how the tables <strong>an</strong>d figures are built, we refer to Section 4.2.<br />

38 See, for example, AA-rated coupon bond vs. government bond, 1 year investment horizon. This is<br />

particularly the c<strong>as</strong>e if no defaults have taken place, which c<strong>an</strong> be attributed to the number of simulations.<br />

For a discussion, we refer to Section 7.1.4.<br />

39 See Figures 7.4, 7.5, 7.27 <strong>an</strong>d 7.28.<br />

151


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

To obtain a deeper insight into the return distributions, we show the empirical distri-<br />

bution functions <strong>an</strong>d the distribution functions split into tail <strong>an</strong>d rest of the distribution<br />

in Figures 7.29, 7.30 <strong>an</strong>d 7.31 for the 1 year investment horizon. The corresponding dis-<br />

tribution functions for the 3 years investment horizon are shown in Figures 7.32, 7.33 <strong>an</strong>d<br />

7.34.<br />

From these figures, we c<strong>an</strong> see a non-normality of the distributions, if defaults have<br />

taken place. Moreover, we recognise again that for the 1 year investment horizon, the<br />

CDS <strong>an</strong>d the CDS index have considerably less volatility th<strong>an</strong> government <strong>an</strong>d corporate<br />

bonds, while having a similar expected return to government bonds.<br />

The linear correlations between the returns of the fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments for the invest-<br />

ment horizons 1 year, 3 years <strong>an</strong>d 5 years are displayed in Figure 7.35.<br />

Regarding the correlation matrices, we make the similar observations <strong>as</strong> for low default<br />

correlation between the reference entities. 40<br />

• Bond returns have a high positive correlation for a 1 year <strong>an</strong>d 3 years investment<br />

horizon.<br />

• Bond <strong>an</strong>d equity index returns are negatively correlated for a 1 year <strong>an</strong>d 3 years<br />

investment horizon.<br />

• There is a small positive or negative correlation between returns of bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS<br />

or the CDS index for a 1 year <strong>an</strong>d 3 years investment horizon.<br />

• The returns of the equity index <strong>an</strong>d CDS or CDS index are positively correlated.<br />

40 For <strong>an</strong> interpretation of the correlations, we refer to Section 7.1.4.<br />

152


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.27: Key statistics US economy, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults<br />

153


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.28: Key statistics US economy, NIG defaults<br />

154


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.29: Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 1 year time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults<br />

(left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

155


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.30: Left tail densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 1 year time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

Figure 7.31: Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments without left tails, 1 year time horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

156


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.32: Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 3 years time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults<br />

(left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

157


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.33: Left tail densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, 3 years time horizon, Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

Figure 7.34: Densities of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments without left tails, 3 years time horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

158


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.35: Correlation of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments in US economy, Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults <strong>an</strong>d<br />

NIG defaults<br />

159


7.2.2 Me<strong>an</strong>-Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Approach<br />

CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Conducting a me<strong>an</strong> vari<strong>an</strong>ce-optimisation according to the optimisation problem (6.1) with<br />

the different investment universes listed in Remark 7.1, we obtain the efficient frontiers<br />

<strong>an</strong>d optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocations shown in the figures below.<br />

All in all, the observations are similar to those in Section 7.1.5. Considering the<br />

efficient frontiers, we see again <strong>an</strong> upward shift of the efficient frontier when allowing for<br />

corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d a shift to the left, when allowing additionally for CDS/CDS index,<br />

i.e. a potential to reduce risk. These shifts c<strong>an</strong> be attributed to a low correlation between<br />

the fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>sets <strong>an</strong>d to the appealing risk-return profile of these instruments. 41<br />

Now, we <strong>an</strong>alyse the optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocations according to the me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce cri-<br />

terium. The following results c<strong>an</strong> mainly be explained by the risk-return profile of the<br />

instruments <strong>an</strong>d the correlation structure between them.<br />

• The main observation is that government bonds are totally or partially substituted<br />

with corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS index.<br />

• In contr<strong>as</strong>t to the lower default correlation, now optimal allocations contain CDS<br />

up to a higher level of st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation: For levels of st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation higher<br />

th<strong>an</strong> 6.91% (Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default time) <strong>an</strong>d 6.74% (NIG) <strong>an</strong> optimal portfolio only<br />

consists of corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> equity index for a 1 year horizon. These limits<br />

are approximately 1% lower for the lower default correlation. We make a similar<br />

observation for the 3 years time horizon <strong>an</strong>d NIG default time. This result c<strong>an</strong><br />

be explained by the risk-return profile of the BBB-rated CDS. 42 The BBB-rated<br />

CDS, for example, generates a rather high expected return compared to its st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

deviation. 43 Compared to the BBB-rated CDS return for low default correlation 44<br />

it h<strong>as</strong> a more attractive risk-return profile. Its expected return is higher for higher<br />

default correlation, while its st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation is lower.<br />

Figure 7.36 shows the potential return enh<strong>an</strong>cement for different investment universes,<br />

b<strong>as</strong>ed on the same level of risk <strong>as</strong> the minimum-vari<strong>an</strong>ce portfolio in the initial investment<br />

universe. The results are very similar to those in Section 7.1.5.<br />

After having <strong>an</strong>alysed the results of the higher default correlation <strong>an</strong>d compared to<br />

the results of the lower default correlation, we c<strong>an</strong> draw the following conclusions. An<br />

investor applying the me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce criterium for portfolio selection c<strong>an</strong> add perform<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

to his portfolio for a given level of risk, or he c<strong>an</strong> reduce risk for a target return level. This<br />

c<strong>an</strong> be achieved due to the low correlation <strong>an</strong>d the risk-return profile of the instruments<br />

by partially replacing his government bond investment by a combination of corporate<br />

bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS index. The optimal allocations, however, vary somewhat between<br />

the different default correlations, particularly for low levels of risk.<br />

41 See Figures 7.35, 7.27 <strong>an</strong>d 7.28.<br />

42 Having a closer look at the simulation results, it turns out, that for higher levels of st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation<br />

only BBB-rated CDS are contained in the optimal allocations.<br />

43 BBB-rated CDS, for example, dominates the government bonds, i.e. it h<strong>as</strong> a higher expected return,<br />

but a lower st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation.<br />

44 See Figures 7.4 <strong>an</strong>d 7.5.<br />

160


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.36: Minimum-vari<strong>an</strong>ce portfolio with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d<br />

NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

161


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.37: Results of me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimisation, 1 year investment horizon with<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

162


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.38: Results of me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimisation, 3 years investment horizon with<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

163


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.39: Results of me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimisation, 5 years investment horizon with<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

164


7.2.3 Conditional Value at Risk<br />

CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

In <strong>an</strong>alogy to Section 7.1.6, we conduct a CVaR-optimisation according to the optimisation<br />

problem (6.7) with the investment universes listed in Remark 7.1. The resulting efficient<br />

frontiers <strong>an</strong>d optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocations are displayed in the figures below.<br />

The main observations are similar to those in Section 7.1.6. When we regard the<br />

efficient frontiers, we see again <strong>an</strong> upward shift of the efficient frontier if the investment<br />

universe is extended by corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d a shift to the left, if the investment universe<br />

is additionally extended by CDS/CDS index. The latter extension particularly me<strong>an</strong>s a<br />

potential to reduce risk. These shifts c<strong>an</strong> be attributed to a low correlation between the<br />

fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>sets <strong>an</strong>d to the appealing risk-return profile of these instruments. 45<br />

• The main observation is that government bonds are totally substituted with corpo-<br />

rate bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS index. For the lower default correlation in contr<strong>as</strong>t, we<br />

see a high proportion of government bonds for the 5 years investment horizon with<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times, due to the risk-return profile of the instruments.<br />

• Now, for the higher default correlation between reference entities, optimal allocations<br />

contain CDS up to a higher level of CVaR, in contr<strong>as</strong>t to the lower default correlation:<br />

For levels of CVaR higher th<strong>an</strong> 6.91% (Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default time) <strong>an</strong>d 6.35% (NIG) <strong>an</strong><br />

optimal portfolio only consists of corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> equity index for a 1 year<br />

horizon. These limits are more th<strong>an</strong> 1% lower for the lower default correlation. 46<br />

This result c<strong>an</strong> be explained by the risk-return profile of the BBB-rated CDS. 47 The<br />

BBB-rated CDS, for example, generates a rather high expected return compared<br />

to its CVaR. 48 Compared to the BBB-rated CDS return for low default correlation<br />

it h<strong>as</strong> a more attractive risk-return profile. Its expected return is higher for higher<br />

default correlation, while its CVaR is lower.<br />

• For the 3 years investment horizon <strong>an</strong>d for Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times, the proportion<br />

of CDS is considerably lower for the higher default correlation th<strong>an</strong> for the lower<br />

one. Having a closer look at the optimal allocations reveals a very large proportion<br />

of A-rated CDS in the c<strong>as</strong>e of low default correlation. This c<strong>an</strong> be explained by two<br />

facts: First, the more attractive risk-return profile of A-rated CDS within the 3 year<br />

time horizon for Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times <strong>an</strong>d low default correlation. Second, the<br />

more attractive risk-return profile of A-rated CDS compared to the same instrument<br />

for high default correlation.<br />

Figure 7.40 shows the potential expected return enh<strong>an</strong>cement for different investment<br />

universes, b<strong>as</strong>ed on the same level of CVaR <strong>as</strong> the minimum-CVaR portfolio in the initial<br />

investment universe.<br />

The results slightly differ from those in Section 7.1.6. This c<strong>an</strong> be attributed to different<br />

risk-return profiles of the fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments for different default correlations <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

45<br />

See Figures 7.35, 7.27 <strong>an</strong>d 7.28.<br />

46<br />

See Section 7.1.6.<br />

47<br />

A closer look at the simulation results reveals that for higher levels of CVaR only BBB-rated CDS<br />

are contained in the optimal allocations.<br />

48<br />

The BBB-rated CDS, for example, dominates the government bonds, i.e. it h<strong>as</strong> a higher expected<br />

return, but a considerably lower CVaR.<br />

165


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.40: Minimum-CVaR portfolio with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG<br />

defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

resulting optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocations. Though, it becomes obvious that <strong>an</strong> enormous return<br />

enh<strong>an</strong>cement c<strong>an</strong> be achieved by extending the investment universe by credit-risk bearing<br />

instruments.<br />

To sum up, <strong>an</strong> investor applying the CVaR criterium for portfolio selection, c<strong>an</strong> add<br />

perform<strong>an</strong>ce to his portfolio for a given level of risk, or he c<strong>an</strong> reduce risk for a target<br />

return level. This c<strong>an</strong> be achieved due to the low correlation <strong>an</strong>d the risk-return profile of<br />

the instruments by substituting government bonds by a combination of corporate bonds<br />

<strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS index. The optimal allocations between the two <strong>an</strong>alysed levels of default<br />

correlation, however, partly differ from each other, particularly for low levels of CVaR.<br />

166


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.41: Results of CVaR optimisation, 1 year investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

167


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.42: Results of CVaR optimisation, 3 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

168


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.43: Results of CVaR optimisation, 5 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

169


7.2.4 Score<br />

CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Finally, we also conduct the score optimisation according to optimisation problem (6.14),<br />

<strong>an</strong>alogous to Section 7.1.7. Again, we consider two representative investors with bench-<br />

mark portfolios <strong>as</strong> given in Table 7.8. The figures below show the optimisation results.<br />

Figure 7.44: Results of score optimisation, 1 year investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

The main observations are similar to those in Section 7.1.7. All observations <strong>an</strong>d<br />

differences to the low default correlation c<strong>an</strong> be attributed to the specific characteristics of<br />

the optimisation procedure 49 , the risk-return profiles of the instruments <strong>an</strong>d the correlation<br />

between them. 50<br />

• All investors have a lower proportion of the equity index in their optimal portfolio<br />

th<strong>an</strong> the benchmark portfolio. The optimal allocation never contains government<br />

bonds. In contr<strong>as</strong>t to that, the optimal allocation for the lower default correlation<br />

contains government bonds for the risk-averse investor with a 5 years time horizon<br />

with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times.<br />

• The proportion of the equity index is rather similar for both default correlations in<br />

most of the c<strong>as</strong>es. There is one major exception: Applying NIG default times, <strong>an</strong><br />

investor with a 1 year time horizon should invest a considerably lower proportion<br />

into the equity index <strong>an</strong>d a considerably larger proportion into CDS (BBB-rated). 51<br />

49 For a discussion, we refer to Section 7.1.7.<br />

50 See Figures 7.27 <strong>an</strong>d 7.28 <strong>an</strong>d 7.35.<br />

51 This phenomenon w<strong>as</strong> already explained in Sections 7.2.2 <strong>an</strong>d 7.2.3.<br />

170


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.45: Results of score optimisation, 3 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

• Risk-averse investors for the 3 years investment horizon should also have a slightly<br />

higher proportion of CDS in their portfolio for the higher default correlation.<br />

• Regarding the resulting expected portfolio returns there is no clear trend between<br />

both default correlations. Sometimes, it is higher with the higher default correlation<br />

th<strong>an</strong> for the lower one <strong>an</strong>d sometimes it is the other way round. We make the same<br />

observation for score values.<br />

The results show that <strong>an</strong> investor optimising his portfolio with the score me<strong>as</strong>ure c<strong>an</strong><br />

obtain a better risk-return profile compared to his benchmark portfolio. This c<strong>an</strong> be<br />

achieved by substituting government bonds with corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS index.<br />

171


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.46: Results of score optimisation, 5 years investment horizon with Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

defaults (left-h<strong>an</strong>d side) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (right-h<strong>an</strong>d side)<br />

172


7.2.5 Comparison of Optimal Portfolios<br />

CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Now we show the optimal portfolio allocations for a risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d a risk-affine investor<br />

having a benchmark portfolio listed in Table 7.8, <strong>an</strong>alogous to Section 7.1.8. For the<br />

investment universe allowing for all instruments, we display the optimal portfolios with<br />

the same st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation <strong>an</strong>d CVaR, respectively, <strong>as</strong> the benchmark portfolio. Besides,<br />

we display the corresponding optimal portfolio according to score optimisation. The data<br />

for the me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d CVaR-optimal portfolios is taken from the optimisation output<br />

presented in Sections 7.2.2 <strong>an</strong>d 7.2.3. The data for the score optimisation c<strong>an</strong> be found in<br />

Section 7.2.4. The results are shown in the following figures.<br />

Figure 7.47: Results for risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d risk-affine investor, 1 year investment horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (top) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (bottom)<br />

The main results are similar to those in Section 7.1.8. We see similar resulting ex-<br />

pected portfolio returns <strong>an</strong>d portfolio allocations for me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d CVaR optimisa-<br />

tion. Again, the portfolio returns from CVaR optimisation are higher th<strong>an</strong> for the other<br />

optimisation procedures.<br />

Comparing resulting expected portfolio returns, we c<strong>an</strong>not reveal a clear trend between<br />

both default correlations. In some c<strong>as</strong>es, the expected returns are higher with the higher<br />

default correlation th<strong>an</strong> with the lower one, <strong>an</strong>d vice versa.<br />

In contr<strong>as</strong>t to the lower default correlation, we observe here a considerable proportion<br />

of CDS in <strong>an</strong> optimal allocation for a risk-averse investor with a 1 year time-horizon. 52<br />

To conclude, comparing the resulting optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocations for a representative<br />

risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d risk-affine investor, we see that independent from investment horizon, op-<br />

timisation criterium <strong>an</strong>d default correlation between reference entities, <strong>an</strong> investor always<br />

benefits from (partially) substituting government bonds by corporate bonds <strong>an</strong>d CDS/CDS<br />

index.<br />

52 We already explained this phenomenon earlier in Sections 7.2.2 <strong>an</strong>d 7.2.3.<br />

173


CHAPTER 7. SIMULATION AND SIMULATION RESULTS<br />

Figure 7.48: Results for risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d risk-affine investor, 3 years investment horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (top) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (bottom)<br />

Figure 7.49: Results for risk-averse <strong>an</strong>d risk-affine investor, 5 years investment horizon,<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> defaults (top) <strong>an</strong>d NIG defaults (bottom)<br />

174


Chapter 8<br />

Summary <strong>an</strong>d Outlook<br />

In this thesis, we aimed at giving a deep underst<strong>an</strong>ding of credit instruments <strong>an</strong>d at<br />

<strong>an</strong>alysing these instruments in a portfolio context with a consistent <strong>as</strong>set allocation frame-<br />

work, which comprises a simulation, pricing <strong>an</strong>d optimisation framework.<br />

Therefore, Chapter 2 gave a deep <strong>an</strong>d comprehensive insight into credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer.<br />

After having explained some regulatory <strong>as</strong>pects regarding credit risk, we described the<br />

traditional credit related instruments, lo<strong>an</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d bonds. They often build the underlyings<br />

for credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer. Then, the main vehicles to tr<strong>an</strong>sfer credit risk were introduced,<br />

which are credit derivatives <strong>an</strong>d securitisations. We presented the functionality of these<br />

instruments, the re<strong>as</strong>ons for using them, <strong>an</strong>d both, ch<strong>an</strong>ces <strong>an</strong>d risks related to these<br />

markets. This chapter closed with <strong>an</strong> overview on market evolution <strong>an</strong>d size.<br />

Chapter 3 w<strong>as</strong> dedicated to single credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer instruments. After a cl<strong>as</strong>sifica-<br />

tion of credit risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer instruments according to the dimensions unfunded/funded, i.e.<br />

without or with initial investment of the protection seller, <strong>an</strong>d single-name/multi-name,<br />

i.e. one or several underlying reference entities, we explained the most import<strong>an</strong>t instru-<br />

ments. In particular, these instruments are CDS, total return swaps, credit spread options,<br />

b<strong>as</strong>ket CDS, portfolio CDS, credit linked notes, collateralised debt obligations <strong>an</strong>d CDS<br />

indices. We mainly focussed on CDS <strong>an</strong>d CDS indices because they are the most liquid<br />

instruments in the market. For this re<strong>as</strong>on they were also used in the <strong>as</strong>set allocation<br />

framework to represent credit derivatives.<br />

In Chapter 4, we <strong>an</strong>alysed Lehm<strong>an</strong> aggregate indices, which are fixed income indices,<br />

to learn more about distributional properties of returns of credit instruments. Statistical<br />

tests for normality for several US- <strong>an</strong>d Euro-aggregate indices clearly rejected that the<br />

returns were normally distributed. We saw heavily tailed distributions, particularly for<br />

negative returns, which potentially indicated defaults. As we w<strong>an</strong>ted to develop <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set<br />

allocation framework that is able to map reality <strong>as</strong> good <strong>as</strong> possible, it w<strong>as</strong> necessary to<br />

set up a simulation <strong>an</strong>d pricing system that c<strong>an</strong> create return distributions accounting for<br />

the distinct properties of credit instruments.<br />

Chapter 5 presented a c<strong>as</strong>cade model allowing to simulate interest-rates, credit spreads<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the spread of a CDS index. To realistically price credit instruments, we needed to<br />

take into account potential defaults. Therefore, this chapter introduced the popular one-<br />

factor copula approach for modelling correlated default times. We used this approach not<br />

only for a Gaussi<strong>an</strong> one-factor copula, but also for a Normal-Inverse-Gaussi<strong>an</strong> (NIG) one-<br />

175


CHAPTER 8. SUMMARY AND OUTLOOK<br />

factor copula, because the latter is able to produce default times with a higher probability<br />

of joint defaults between reference entities th<strong>an</strong> the Gaussi<strong>an</strong> version. This is a more<br />

realistic <strong>as</strong>sumption, since, for example, during a recession more firms default th<strong>an</strong> during<br />

a booming period. We calculated the distribution function for default times with migration<br />

matrices provided by rating agencies. Finally, we introduced the pricing formul<strong>as</strong> for<br />

the credit instruments in the relev<strong>an</strong>t investment universe: Zero-coupon bonds, coupon<br />

bonds, funded CDS <strong>an</strong>d funded CDS indices. In order to price CDS <strong>an</strong>d CDS indices,<br />

it w<strong>as</strong> necessary to know expected losses, which were determined by the const<strong>an</strong>t default<br />

intensity model.<br />

Chapter 6 completed the <strong>as</strong>set allocation framework. In order to find optimal portfo-<br />

lios, we first considered the me<strong>an</strong>-vari<strong>an</strong>ce approach according to Markowitz. The follow-<br />

ing discussion showed some problems, either driven by strict <strong>as</strong>sumptions on the structure<br />

of <strong>as</strong>set returns, such <strong>as</strong> normal distributions, or driven by strict <strong>as</strong>sumptions on utility<br />

functions. As seen earlier, returns of credit instruments were not normally distributed.<br />

Therefore, other optimisation procedures accounting for the distinct distributional prop-<br />

erties of credit instruments were presented. One appropriate risk me<strong>as</strong>ure for the optimi-<br />

sation is the conditional value at risk, which is roughly speaking the expected value of all<br />

losses exceeding a certain signific<strong>an</strong>ce level. With this me<strong>as</strong>ure, the complete tail distri-<br />

bution of fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments is considered. The l<strong>as</strong>t section w<strong>as</strong> dedicated to portfolio<br />

selection with the me<strong>as</strong>ure score. This me<strong>as</strong>ure takes into account <strong>an</strong> investor’s risk-<br />

aversion <strong>an</strong>d the entire upside <strong>an</strong>d downside potential of a portfolio distribution related<br />

to a fixed target return.<br />

We applied the <strong>as</strong>set allocation framework to investors in the United States. In Chapter<br />

7, we presented the simulation <strong>an</strong>d optimisation results. On the one h<strong>an</strong>d, the model<br />

parameters for the GDP growth rate, the inflation rate, the short-rate, the credit spreads<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the equity index were presented. In addition, the starting curve for the US zero<br />

rates w<strong>as</strong> fitted to market data <strong>as</strong> of 30 th of September, 2006 (simulation start date). On<br />

the other h<strong>an</strong>d, the parameters for the correlated default times were also provided <strong>as</strong> of<br />

simulation start date. At that day, the default correlation between two reference entities<br />

w<strong>as</strong> only at 0.13771.<br />

After having calculated the risk-return profiles of all instruments in the investment<br />

universe <strong>an</strong>d the optimal allocations for the investment horizons 1 year, 3 years <strong>an</strong>d 5<br />

years, we found that the risk-return profiles of the credit instruments were very attrac-<br />

tive compared to government bonds. Particularly in a 1 year investment horizon, CDS<br />

(AA- or A-rated) <strong>an</strong>d the CDS index had a considerably lower risk (me<strong>as</strong>ured in st<strong>an</strong>-<br />

dard deviation or CVaR) th<strong>an</strong> government bonds, while having nearly the same expected<br />

return. However, it also became obvious that the returns could be strongly non-normal<br />

for credit instruments, which w<strong>as</strong> caused by defaults. Besides, the correlations between<br />

the returns of different instruments were rather low due to distinct characteristics of the<br />

instruments under consideration. So, investors could benefit from diversification effects in<br />

their portfolios by adding credit instruments.<br />

Independent of the applied investment horizon, default time or optimisation criterium,<br />

a shift of the efficient frontier compared to the efficient frontier of the initial investment<br />

universe (government bonds <strong>an</strong>d equity index) w<strong>as</strong> observed. After extending the invest-<br />

176


CHAPTER 8. SUMMARY AND OUTLOOK<br />

ment universe by corporate bonds, CDS <strong>an</strong>d a CDS index, we saw a shift of the efficient<br />

frontier – either <strong>an</strong> upward shift or a shift to the left. Consequently, <strong>an</strong> investor could en-<br />

h<strong>an</strong>ce the expected portfolio return for a given level of risk, or he could reduce portfolio risk<br />

for a target return level by partially replacing the government bond investment by credit<br />

instruments. The optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocations always contained a considerable proportion of<br />

corporate bonds, CDS or a CDS index.<br />

As explained earlier, the actual default correlation between the reference entities w<strong>as</strong><br />

rather low at simulation start date. For this re<strong>as</strong>on, we also performed the simulation<br />

<strong>an</strong>d optimisation with a default correlation of 0.3. Regarding the risk-return profiles<br />

of the credit instruments, we detected that with a decre<strong>as</strong>ing credit quality the return<br />

distribution of single instruments priced with NIG default times became even more non-<br />

normal compared to pricing with Gaussi<strong>an</strong> default times. This could be attributed to<br />

the realistic ability of the NIG distribution to generate more joint defaults for relatively<br />

small time horizons. We also saw that within one default time, i.e. only considering<br />

the Gaussi<strong>an</strong> or NIG default time, the return distributions were more non-normal with<br />

default correlation of 0.3. This could be attributed to the ability of the one-factor copula<br />

to generate more joint defaults within a relatively small time horizon for a higher default<br />

correlation, given a certain rating cl<strong>as</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d a certain one-factor copula.<br />

The general observations, however, were similar to a low default correlation. The<br />

efficient frontier of the initial investment universe also experienced a shift by extending the<br />

investment universe by credit instruments. Moreover, optimal allocations always contained<br />

a considerable proportion of corporate bonds, CDS or a CDS index, too.<br />

All in all, with the presented <strong>as</strong>set allocation framework, the following central results<br />

were found: <strong>Credit</strong> instruments have <strong>an</strong> appealing risk-return profile, allowing to enh<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

the expected portfolio return compared to a portfolio of traditional <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses, such <strong>as</strong><br />

equity indices <strong>an</strong>d government bonds. Due to the correlation structure between returns of<br />

credit instruments <strong>an</strong>d those of traditional <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses, credit instruments offer enormous<br />

diversification potential.<br />

B<strong>as</strong>ed on the findings described above, we c<strong>an</strong> actually consider credit instruments<br />

<strong>as</strong> a single <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s. Every investor, independent of his risk-aversion <strong>an</strong>d optimisation<br />

criterium, c<strong>an</strong> profit from adding credit instruments to his portfolio.<br />

The framework presented in this thesis c<strong>an</strong> be the starting point for further research:<br />

At the moment, CDS <strong>an</strong>d CDS indices have only been considered <strong>as</strong> me<strong>an</strong>s of investment.<br />

One field of research c<strong>an</strong> be the <strong>an</strong>alysis of CDS <strong>an</strong>d CDS indices <strong>as</strong> me<strong>an</strong>s of hedging,<br />

too. Then, the investor would act <strong>as</strong> protection buyer, rather th<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong> protection seller, by<br />

shorting funded CDS or a CDS index.<br />

Another subject for further research c<strong>an</strong> be the extension of the investment universe<br />

by other credit instruments, such <strong>as</strong> CDOs or other structured credit products, in general.<br />

So, there might be more potential to diversify one’s portfolio by low-correlated returns.<br />

From this research, we should learn even more about the implications on optimal <strong>as</strong>set<br />

allocations for different types of investors.<br />

177


Appendix A<br />

Mathematical Preliminaries <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Definitions<br />

In this chapter we w<strong>an</strong>t to provide the mathematical preliminaries relev<strong>an</strong>t for this thesis.<br />

We use [Zag02] <strong>an</strong>d [BK04], for the description of the theory.<br />

A.1 Probability Spaces <strong>an</strong>d Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Processes<br />

Definition A.1 (σ-Algebra)<br />

If Ω is a given set, then a σ-algebra F on Ω is a family F of subsets of Ω with the following<br />

properties:<br />

(a) Ω ∈ F,<br />

(b) A ∈ F ⇒ A C = Ω\A ∈ F,<br />

(c) A1, A2, . . . ∈ F ⇒ A := ∞�<br />

Ai ∈ F.<br />

i=1<br />

Definition A.2 (Me<strong>as</strong>urable Space)<br />

The pair (Ω, F) is called a me<strong>as</strong>urable space.<br />

Definition A.3 (Probability Me<strong>as</strong>ure)<br />

A probability me<strong>as</strong>ure Q on a me<strong>as</strong>urable space (Ω, F) is a function P : F −→ [0, 1]<br />

such that<br />

(a) Q(∅) = 0, Q(Ω) = 1.<br />

�<br />

(b) If A1, A2, . . . ∈ F are disjoint (i.e. Ai Aj = ∅ if i �= j) then<br />

Definition A.4 (Probability Space)<br />

∞�<br />

Q( Ai) =<br />

i=1<br />

∞�<br />

Q(Ai).<br />

The triple (Ω, F, Q) is called a probability space. A set A ∈ F with Q(A) = 0 is called<br />

a (Q−) null set. (Ω, F, Q) is called a complete probability space if F contains all subsets<br />

of the (Q−) null sets.<br />

178<br />

i=1


APPENDIX A. MATHEMATICAL PRELIMINARIES AND DEFINITIONS<br />

To define stoch<strong>as</strong>tic processes we additionally introduce filtered probability spaces.<br />

Definition A.5 (Filtration)<br />

A filtration F is a non-decre<strong>as</strong>ing family of sub-sigma-algebr<strong>as</strong> (Ft)t≥0 with Ft ⊂ F <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Fs ⊂ Ft for all 0 ≤ s < t < ∞. We call (Ω, F, Q, F) a filtered probability space, <strong>an</strong>d<br />

require that<br />

(a) F0 contains all subsets of the (Q−) null sets of F,<br />

(b) F is right-continuous, i.e. Ft = Ft+ := ∩s>tFs.<br />

(Ω, F, Q, F) is a complete filtered probability space, if F <strong>an</strong>d each Ft, 0 ≤ s < t < ∞,<br />

is complete. One c<strong>an</strong> think of Ft <strong>as</strong> the information available at time t, <strong>an</strong>d F = (Ft)t≥0<br />

describes the complete flow of information over time <strong>as</strong>suming that no information is lost<br />

in the course of time.<br />

To describe the behavior of the fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments, their volatility <strong>an</strong>d correlation,<br />

we use stoch<strong>as</strong>tic processes.<br />

Definition A.6 (Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Process)<br />

A stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process is a family X = (Xt)t≥0 = (X(t))t≥0 of r<strong>an</strong>dom variables Xt de-<br />

fined on the filtered probability space (Ω, F, Q, F). The stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process X is called<br />

(a) adapted to the filtration F if Xt = X(t) is Ft− me<strong>as</strong>urable for all t ≥ 0,<br />

(b) me<strong>as</strong>urable if the mapping X : [0, ∞) × Ω −→ R k , k ∈ N, is (B([0, ∞)) ⊗ F −<br />

B(R k )−) me<strong>as</strong>urable with B([0, ∞)) ⊗ F denoting the product sigma-algebra created<br />

by B([0, ∞)) <strong>an</strong>d F,<br />

(c) progressively me<strong>as</strong>urable if the mapping X : [0, t]×Ω −→ R k , k ∈ N, is (B([0, t])⊗<br />

Ft − B(R k )) me<strong>as</strong>urable for each t ≥ 0.<br />

Note that for each t fixed, we have a r<strong>an</strong>dom variable<br />

with ω ∈ Ω.<br />

ω −→ Xt(ω),<br />

When fixing ω ∈ Ω, we have a function in t, i.e.<br />

called a path of Xt.<br />

t −→ Xt(ω),<br />

An import<strong>an</strong>t example for a stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process is the Wiener process, denoted by<br />

W = (Wt)t≥0 = (W (t))t≥0. Sometimes it is also called Browni<strong>an</strong> motion.<br />

Definition A.7 (Wiener Process)<br />

Let (Ω, F, Q, F) be a filtered probability space. The stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process W = (Wt)t≥0 =<br />

(W (t))t≥0 is called a (Q−) Browni<strong>an</strong> motion or (Q−) Wiener process if<br />

(a) W (0) = 0 Q− a.s.,<br />

179


APPENDIX A. MATHEMATICAL PRELIMINARIES AND DEFINITIONS<br />

(b) W h<strong>as</strong> independent increments, i.e. W (t) − W (s) is independent of W (t ′<br />

) − W (s ′<br />

)<br />

for all 0 ≤ s ′<br />

≤ t ′<br />

≤ s ≤ t < ∞,<br />

(c) W h<strong>as</strong> stationary increments, i.e. the distribution of W (t + u) − W (t) only depends<br />

on u for u ≥ 0,<br />

(d) Under Q, W h<strong>as</strong> Gaussi<strong>an</strong> increments, i.e. W (t + u) − W (t) ∼ N(0, u),<br />

(e) W h<strong>as</strong> continuous paths Q− a.s..<br />

We call W , W = (W1, . . . , Wm) = (W1(t), . . . , Wm(t))t≥0 a m-dimensional Wiener<br />

process, m ∈ N, if its components Wj, j = 1, . . . , m, m ∈ N, are independent Wiener<br />

processes.<br />

One b<strong>as</strong>ic concept for modelling in fin<strong>an</strong>ce, is the so-called martingale.<br />

Definition A.8 (Martingale)<br />

Let (Ω, F, Q, F) be a filtered probability space. A stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process X = (X(t))t≥0 is called<br />

a martingale relative to (Q, F) if X is adapted, EQ[|X(t)|] < ∞ for all t ≥ 0, <strong>an</strong>d<br />

EQ = [X(t)|Fs] = X(s) Q − a.s. for all 0 ≤ s ≤ t < ∞.<br />

A.2 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Differential Equations<br />

A tool to describe the behaviour of fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>sets <strong>an</strong>d derivatives is the Itô Process.<br />

Definition A.9 (Itô Process)<br />

Let Wt be a m-dimensional Wiener process, m ∈ N. A stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process X = (X(t))t≥0<br />

is called <strong>an</strong> Itô process if for all t ≥ 0 we have<br />

X(t) = X(0) +<br />

= X(0) +<br />

� t<br />

0<br />

� t<br />

0<br />

µ(s)ds +<br />

µ(s)ds +<br />

� t<br />

0<br />

m�<br />

j=1<br />

σ(s)dW (s) (A.1)<br />

� t<br />

0<br />

σj(s)dWj(s),<br />

where X(0) is (F0−) me<strong>as</strong>urable <strong>an</strong>d µ = (µ(t))t≥0 <strong>an</strong>d σ = (σ(t))t≥0 are m-dimensional<br />

progressively me<strong>as</strong>urable stoch<strong>as</strong>tic processes with<br />

� t<br />

0<br />

� t<br />

0<br />

|µ(s)| ds < ∞ (A.2)<br />

σ 2 j (s)ds < ∞ Q − a.s. for all t ≥ 0, j = 1, . . . , m. (A.3)<br />

A n-dimensional Itô process is given by a vector X = (X1, . . . , Xn), n ∈ N, with each Xi<br />

being <strong>an</strong> Itô process, i = 1, . . . , n.<br />

Remark A.10<br />

For convenience we write (A.1) symbolically<br />

dX(t) = µ(t)dt + σ(t)dW (t) = µ(t)dt +<br />

m�<br />

σj(t)dWj(t), (A.4)<br />

j=1<br />

180


APPENDIX A. MATHEMATICAL PRELIMINARIES AND DEFINITIONS<br />

<strong>an</strong>d call this stoch<strong>as</strong>tic differential equation (SDE) with drift parameter µ <strong>an</strong>d diffu-<br />

sion parameter σ.<br />

To use Itô’s Lemma, we have to define the quadratic covari<strong>an</strong>ce process.<br />

Definition A.11 (Quadratic Covari<strong>an</strong>ce Process)<br />

Let m ∈ N <strong>an</strong>d W = (W1(t), . . . , Wm(t))t≥0 <strong>an</strong>d X2 = (X2(t))t≥0 be two Itô processes with<br />

dXi(t) = µi(t)dt + σi(t)dW (t) = µi(t)dt +<br />

m�<br />

σij(t)dWj(t), i = 1, 2.<br />

Then we call the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process 〈X1, X2〉 = (〈X1, X2〉 t )t≥0 defined by<br />

〈X1, X2〉 t :=<br />

m�<br />

j=1<br />

� t<br />

0<br />

j=1<br />

σ1j(s) · σ2j(s)ds<br />

the quadratic covari<strong>an</strong>ce (process) of X1 <strong>an</strong>d X2. If X1 = X2 =: X we call the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic<br />

process 〈X〉 := 〈X, X〉 the quadratic variation (process) of X, i.e.<br />

where �σ(t)� :=<br />

〈X, X〉 t :=<br />

m�<br />

� t<br />

σ<br />

j=1<br />

0<br />

2 � t<br />

j (s)ds =<br />

0<br />

�σ(x)� 2 ds,<br />

� �m<br />

j=1 σ2 j , t ∈ [0, ∞) denotes the Euclide<strong>an</strong> norm in Rm <strong>an</strong>d σ := σ1.<br />

Theorem A.12 (Itô’s Lemma)<br />

Let W = (W (t))t≥0 be a m-dimensional Wiener process, m ∈ N, <strong>an</strong>d X = (X(t))t≥0 be<br />

<strong>an</strong> Itô process with<br />

dX(t) = µ(t)dt + σ(t)dW (t) = µ(t)dt +<br />

m�<br />

σj(t)dWj(t). (A.5)<br />

Furthermore, let G : R × [0, ∞) −→ R be twice continuously differentiable in the first<br />

variable, with the derivatives denoted by Gx <strong>an</strong>d Gxx, <strong>an</strong>d once continuously differentiable<br />

in the second, with the derivative denoted by Gt. Then we have for all t ∈ [0, ∞)<br />

or briefly<br />

G(X(t), t) = G(X(0), 0) +<br />

+<br />

+ 1<br />

2<br />

� t<br />

0<br />

� t<br />

0<br />

� t<br />

0<br />

j=1<br />

Gx(X(s), s)dX(s)<br />

Gt(X(s), s)ds<br />

Gxx(X(s), s)d 〈X〉 (s)<br />

dG(X(t), t) = (Gt(X(t), t) + Gx(X(t), t)µ(t)<br />

+ 1<br />

2 Gxx(X(t), t) �σ(t)� 2 )dt<br />

+Gx(X(t), t)σ(t)dW (t).<br />

181


APPENDIX A. MATHEMATICAL PRELIMINARIES AND DEFINITIONS<br />

A.3 Equivalent Me<strong>as</strong>ure<br />

Definition A.13 (Equivalent Me<strong>as</strong>ure)<br />

Let Q <strong>an</strong>d ˜ Q be two me<strong>as</strong>ures defined on the same me<strong>as</strong>urable space (Ω, F). We say ˜ Q is<br />

absolutely continuous with respect to Q, written ˜ Q ≪ Q,if ˜ Q(A) = 0 whenever Q(A) = 0,<br />

A ∈ F. If both ˜ Q ≪ Q <strong>an</strong>d Q ≪ ˜ Q, we call Q <strong>an</strong>d ˜ Q equivalent me<strong>as</strong>ures <strong>an</strong>d denote this<br />

by ˜ Q ∼ Q.<br />

The definition of equivalent me<strong>as</strong>ures states that two me<strong>as</strong>ures are equivalent if <strong>an</strong>d<br />

only if they have same null sets.<br />

Definition A.14 (Radon Nikodym Derivative)<br />

Let Q be a sigma-finite me<strong>as</strong>ure <strong>an</strong>d ˜ Q be a me<strong>as</strong>ure on the me<strong>as</strong>urable space (Ω, F) with<br />

˜Q < ∞. Then ˜ Q ≪ Q if <strong>an</strong>d only if there exists <strong>an</strong> integrable function f ≥ 0 Q−a.s. such<br />

that<br />

�<br />

˜Q(A) =<br />

A<br />

fdQ ∀A ∈ F.<br />

f is called the Radon-Nikodym derivative of ˜ Q with respect to Q <strong>an</strong>d is also written <strong>as</strong><br />

f = d ˜ Q<br />

dQ .<br />

Let γ = (γ(t))t≥0 be a m-dimensional progressively me<strong>as</strong>urable stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process,<br />

m ∈ N, with<br />

� t<br />

0<br />

γ 2 j (s)ds < ∞ Q − a.s. ∀t ≥ 0, j = 1, . . . , m<br />

Let the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process L(γ) = (L(γ, t))t≥0 = (L(γ(t), t))t≥0, ∀t ≥ 0 be defined by<br />

L(γ, t) = e − � t<br />

0 γ(s)′ dW (s)− 1 � t<br />

2 0 ||γ(s)||ds<br />

Note that the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process X(γ) = (X(γ, t))t≥0 = (X(γ(t), t))t≥0 with<br />

or<br />

X(γ, t) :=<br />

� t<br />

0<br />

γ(s) ′ dW (s) + 1<br />

2<br />

� t<br />

0<br />

||γ(s)|| 2 ds<br />

dX(γ, t) := 1<br />

2 ||γ(t)||2 dt + γ(t) ′ dW (t)<br />

is ∀t ∈ [0, ∞) <strong>an</strong> Itô process with µ(γ(t), t) = 1<br />

2 ||γ(t)||2 = 1<br />

2<br />

�m j=1 γ2 j (t) <strong>an</strong>d σ(γ(t), t) =<br />

γ(t) ′ . Thus, using the tr<strong>an</strong>sformation G : R × [0, ∞) ↦→ R with G(x, t) = e −x <strong>an</strong>d Itô’s<br />

Lemma (Theorem A.12) with G(X(γ, t), t) = e −X(γ,t) = L(γ, t) we obtain: 1<br />

Lemma A.15 (Novikov Condition)<br />

dL(γ, t) = −L(γ, t)γ(t) ′ dW (t)<br />

Let γ <strong>an</strong>d L(γ) be <strong>as</strong> defined above. Then L(γ) = (L(γ, t)) t∈[0,T ] is a continuous (Q -)<br />

martingale if<br />

EQ<br />

1 For a detailed calculation see [Zag02], p. 33.<br />

�<br />

e 1 � t<br />

2 0 ||γ(s)||2ds �<br />

< ∞.<br />

182


Remark A.16<br />

APPENDIX A. MATHEMATICAL PRELIMINARIES AND DEFINITIONS<br />

Under Novikov’s condition<br />

� T<br />

0<br />

�γ(s)� 2 ds < ∞ Q − a.s.<br />

<strong>an</strong>d � T<br />

�γ(s)� 2 ds < ∞ Q − a.s. for all t ∈ [0, T ]<br />

Remark A.17<br />

0<br />

For each T ≥ 0 we define the me<strong>as</strong>ure ˜ Q = Q L(γ,T ) on the me<strong>as</strong>ure space (Ω, FT ) by<br />

�<br />

˜Q(A) := EQ[1A · L(γ, T )] =<br />

A<br />

L(γ, T )dQ for all A ∈ FT ,<br />

which is a probability me<strong>as</strong>ure if L(γ, T ) is a Q-martingale. In this c<strong>as</strong>e, L(γ, T ) is the<br />

Q-density of ˜ Q, i.e. L(γ, T ) = d ˜ Q<br />

dQ on (Ω, FT ).<br />

In the following, we provide the Girs<strong>an</strong>ov Theorem, which shows how a ( ˜ Q−) Wiener<br />

process ˜ W = ( ˜ W (t)) t∈[0,T ] starting with a (Q−) Wiener process W = (W (t))t≥0 c<strong>an</strong> be<br />

constructed.<br />

Theorem A.18 (Girs<strong>an</strong>ov)<br />

Let W = (W1(t), . . . , Wm(t))t≥0 be a m-dimensional (Q−) Wiener process, m ∈ N, γ, L(γ), ˜ Q,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d T ∈ [0, ∞) be <strong>as</strong> defined above, <strong>an</strong>d the m-dimensional stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process ˜ W =<br />

( ˜ W1, . . . , ˜ Wm) = ( ˜ W1(t), . . . , ˜ Wm(t)) t∈[0,T ] be defined by<br />

i.e.<br />

˜Wj(t) := Wj(t) +<br />

� t<br />

0<br />

γj(s)ds, t ∈ [0, T ], j = 1, . . . , m,<br />

d ˜ W (t) := γ(t)dt + dW (t), t ∈ [0, T ].<br />

If the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process L(γ) = (L(γ, t)) t∈[0,T ] is a (Q−) martingale, then the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic<br />

process ˜ W is a m-dimensional ( ˜ Q−) Wiener process on the me<strong>as</strong>ure space (Ω, FT ).<br />

For γ(t) const<strong>an</strong>t the ch<strong>an</strong>ge of me<strong>as</strong>ure corresponds to a ch<strong>an</strong>ge of drift from µ to µ − γ.<br />

183


Appendix B<br />

Ratings<br />

Rating Description<br />

AA Very strong capacity to meet fin<strong>an</strong>cial commitments<br />

A Strong capacity to meet fin<strong>an</strong>cial commitments, but somewhat susceptible to<br />

adverse economic - conditions <strong>an</strong>d ch<strong>an</strong>ges in circumst<strong>an</strong>ces<br />

BBB Adequate capacity to meet fin<strong>an</strong>cial commitments, but more subject to adverse<br />

economic conditions<br />

BB Less vulnerable in the near-term but faces major ongoing uncertainties to<br />

adverse business, fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>an</strong>d economic conditions<br />

B More vulnerable to adverse business, fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>an</strong>d economic conditions but<br />

currently h<strong>as</strong> the capacity to meet fin<strong>an</strong>cial commitments<br />

CCC Currently vulnerable <strong>an</strong>d dependent on favorable business, fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>an</strong>d economic<br />

conditions to meet fin<strong>an</strong>cial commitments<br />

CC Currently highly vulnerable<br />

C A b<strong>an</strong>kruptcy petition h<strong>as</strong> been filed or similar action taken but payments or<br />

fin<strong>an</strong>cial commitments are continued<br />

D Payment default on fin<strong>an</strong>cial commitments<br />

Table B.1: St<strong>an</strong>dard & Poor’s credit ratings<br />

Ratings in the AAA, AA, A <strong>an</strong>d BBB categories are regarded by the market <strong>as</strong><br />

investment grade.<br />

Ratings in the BB, B, CCC, CC <strong>an</strong>d C categories are regarded <strong>as</strong> having signific<strong>an</strong>t<br />

speculative characteristics.<br />

Ratings from AA to CCC may be modified by the addition of a plus (+) or minus (-)<br />

sign to show relative st<strong>an</strong>ding within the major rating categories. 1<br />

1 See www.st<strong>an</strong>dard<strong>an</strong>dpoors.com.<br />

184


Appendix C<br />

Calculation of the Dynamics of the<br />

CDS Index<br />

With Itô’s Lemma 1 we c<strong>an</strong> calculate the dynamics of the CDS Index. We consider the<br />

CDS index spread <strong>as</strong> weighted spread of n different rating cl<strong>as</strong>ses. The dynamics of the<br />

short spread is given by equation (5.13). Then, the dynamics X of n rating cl<strong>as</strong>ses is given<br />

by<br />

with<br />

⎛ ⎞<br />

X1(t)<br />

⎜ ⎟<br />

⎜ X2(t) ⎟<br />

X(t) = ⎜ ⎟<br />

⎜ ⎟<br />

⎝ . ⎠ , θs<br />

⎛<br />

⎜<br />

= ⎜<br />

⎝<br />

Xn(t)<br />

⎛ ⎞<br />

W1(t)<br />

⎜ ⎟<br />

⎜ W2(t) ⎟<br />

W (t) = ⎜ ⎟<br />

⎜ ⎟<br />

⎝ . ⎠ .<br />

dX(t) = [θs + bsuu(t) − bsωω(t) − <strong>as</strong>s(t)] dt + ΣdW (t), (C.1)<br />

θs1<br />

θs2<br />

.<br />

θsn<br />

⎞<br />

⎛<br />

⎟<br />

⎠ , bsu<br />

⎜<br />

= ⎜<br />

⎝<br />

bsu1<br />

bsu2<br />

.<br />

bsun<br />

⎞<br />

⎛<br />

⎟<br />

⎠ , bsω<br />

⎜<br />

= ⎜<br />

⎝<br />

bsω1<br />

bsω2<br />

.<br />

bsωn<br />

⎞<br />

⎛<br />

⎟<br />

⎠ , <strong>as</strong><br />

⎜<br />

= ⎜<br />

⎝<br />

Wn(t)<br />

Let wT = (w1, w2, ..., wn) be a vector with portfolio weights. We define G(X(t), t) <strong>as</strong><br />

The dynamics of dG(X(t), t) is then given by<br />

dG(X(t), t) = w T dX(t)<br />

<strong>as</strong>1<br />

<strong>as</strong>2<br />

.<br />

<strong>as</strong>n<br />

⎞<br />

⎟<br />

⎠ ,<br />

G(X(t), t) = w T X(t). (C.2)<br />

= w T [θs + bsuu(t) − bsωω(t) − <strong>as</strong>s(t)] dt + w T ΣdW (t). (C.3)<br />

The l<strong>as</strong>t term of equation (C.3) yields to a scalar. We w<strong>an</strong>t to express it <strong>as</strong> product of<br />

two scalars <strong>an</strong>d therefore, we equate:<br />

1 See Theorem A.12.<br />

σ ∗ dW ∗ (t) = w T Σ dW (t)<br />

185


APPENDIX C. CALCULATION OF THE DYNAMICS OF THE CDS INDEX<br />

Comparing the volatilities, we get:<br />

σ ∗2 dt = w T ΣΣ T w dt<br />

⇔ σ ∗2 = w T ΣΣ T w<br />

⇔ σ ∗2 = w T COV [X(t)]w<br />

⇔ σ ∗2 = w T<br />

⎛<br />

⎞<br />

σ1 0 0 . . . 0<br />

⎜<br />

⎟<br />

⎜ 0 σ2 0 . . . 0 ⎟<br />

⎜<br />

⎟<br />

⎜ .<br />

⎝ . ..<br />

⎟<br />

. ⎠ Γ[X(t)]<br />

⎛<br />

σ1 0 0 . . . 0<br />

⎜ 0 σ2 0 . . . 0<br />

⎜ .<br />

⎝ . .. .<br />

0 0 . . . σn<br />

0 0 . . . σn<br />

⎞<br />

⎟<br />

⎠ w,<br />

(C.4)<br />

where Γ[X(t)] is the correlation matrix of X(t). Then, we rewrite equation (C.3) according<br />

to<br />

dG(X(t), t) = w T [θs + bsuu(t) − bsωω(t) − <strong>as</strong>s(t)] dt + σ ∗ dW ∗ (t). (C.5)<br />

In this form, we use the equation to simulate the evolution of the CDS index spread.<br />

186


Appendix D<br />

Tr<strong>an</strong>sition Matrix for Europe<strong>an</strong><br />

Union<br />

The tr<strong>an</strong>sition matrix 1 w<strong>as</strong> adjusted by issuers who withdrew their rating, by normalising<br />

the row sums so that they sum up to one.<br />

AAA AA A BBB BB B CCC/C D<br />

AAA 89.92% 9.26% 0.66% 0.16% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%<br />

AA 0.22% 89.63% 9.63% 0.48% 0.01% 0.01% 0.01% 0.01%<br />

A 0.00% 2.31% 92.27% 5.16% 0.20% 0.03% 0.01% 0.01%<br />

BBB 0.00% 0.22% 5.07% 90.79% 2.79% 0.71% 0.14% 0.29%<br />

BB 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 3.56% 85.18% 9.88% 0.60% 0.79%<br />

B 0.00% 0.00% 0.32% 0.64% 7.37% 79.50% 6.09% 6.09%<br />

CCC/C 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 14.28% 31.43% 54.29%<br />

D 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 100.00%<br />

Table D.1: Europe<strong>an</strong> Union average one-year tr<strong>an</strong>sition rates, 1981 to 2005<br />

1 The tr<strong>an</strong>sition matrix is taken from [Sta06].<br />

187


Appendix E<br />

List of Abbreviations<br />

ABS <strong>Asset</strong>-Backed Security<br />

bp b<strong>as</strong>is point<br />

CVaR Conditional Value at Risk<br />

CBO Collateralised Bond Obligation<br />

CDO Collateralised Debt Obligation<br />

CDS <strong>Credit</strong> Default Swap<br />

CLN <strong>Credit</strong> Linked Note<br />

CLO Collateralised Lo<strong>an</strong> Obligation<br />

CPI Consumer Price Index<br />

CVaR Conditional Value at Risk<br />

EEMEA E<strong>as</strong>tern Europe, Middle E<strong>as</strong>t & Africa<br />

ESG Economic Scenario Generator<br />

etc. et cetera<br />

EURIBOR Europe<strong>an</strong> Interb<strong>an</strong>k Offered Rate<br />

FRN Floating Rate Note<br />

GDP Gross Domestic Product<br />

IIC International Index Comp<strong>an</strong>y<br />

ISDA International Swaps <strong>an</strong>d Derivatives Association<br />

LIBOR London Interb<strong>an</strong>k Offered Rate<br />

MRL Me<strong>an</strong> Reverting Level<br />

MVP Minimum Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Portfolio<br />

NIG Normal Inverse Gaussi<strong>an</strong><br />

OTC Over-the-counter<br />

SDE Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Differential Equation<br />

SPE Special Purpose Entity<br />

SPV Special Purpose Vehicle<br />

TRS Total Return Swap<br />

TMT Telecom, Media, Technology<br />

VaR Value at Risk<br />

188


Bibliography<br />

[ADEH99] Artzner, P., Delbaen, F., Eber, J.-M., Heath, D. (1999): Coherent<br />

Me<strong>as</strong>ures of Risk. Math. Fin<strong>an</strong>ce 9(3), 203-228.<br />

[BC04] Bamberg, G., Coenenberg, A.G. (2004): Betriebswirtschaftliche Entschei-<br />

dungslehre. 12. Auflage, Verlag Vahlen, <strong>München</strong>.<br />

[Bay06] Bayern LB (2006): ABS H<strong>an</strong>dbuch: Einführung in <strong>Asset</strong>-Backed Securities.<br />

[BIS03] B<strong>an</strong>k for International Settlements (2003): <strong>Credit</strong> risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer. Re-<br />

port submitted by a Working Group established by the Committee on the Global<br />

Fin<strong>an</strong>cial System.<br />

[BIS05] B<strong>an</strong>k for International Settlements (2005): International Convergence<br />

of Capital Me<strong>as</strong>urement <strong>an</strong>d Capital St<strong>an</strong>dards.<br />

[BIS05a] B<strong>an</strong>k for International Settlements (2005): <strong>Credit</strong> risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer.<br />

[B<strong>as</strong>04] B<strong>as</strong>eler Ausschuss für B<strong>an</strong>kenaufsicht (2004): Internationale Konver-<br />

genz der Kapitalmessung und Eigenkapital<strong>an</strong>forderungen – Ueberarbeitete Rah-<br />

menvereinbarung (Juni 2004).<br />

[BR04] Bielecki, T., Rutkowski, M. (2004): <strong>Credit</strong> Risk: Modeling, Valuation <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Hedging. 1st Edition 2002. Corrected 2nd printing, Springer.<br />

[BK04] Bingham, N., Kiesel, R. (2004): Risk-Neutral Valuation. Pricing <strong>an</strong>d Hedg-<br />

ing of Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Derivatives. 2nd Edition, Springer.<br />

[Blu03] Bluhm, C. (2003): CDO Modeling: Techniques, Examples <strong>an</strong>d Applications.<br />

Working Paper.<br />

[BOW03] Bluhm, C., Overbeck, L., Wagner, C. (2003): An introduction to credit<br />

risk modeling. Chapm<strong>an</strong> & Hall/CRC, London.<br />

[Bom05] Bomfim, A.N. (2005): Underst<strong>an</strong>ding <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives <strong>an</strong>d Related Instru-<br />

ments. Elsevier Academic Press, S<strong>an</strong> Diego.<br />

[Bri04] British B<strong>an</strong>kers’ Association (2004): BBA <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives Report<br />

2003/2004 – Executive Summary. British B<strong>an</strong>kers’ Association, London.<br />

[Cha05] Chaplin, G. (2005): <strong>Credit</strong> derivatives: risk m<strong>an</strong>agement, trading & investing.<br />

John Wiley & Sons Ltd., Chichester.<br />

189


BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />

[D<strong>as</strong>06] D<strong>as</strong>, S. (2006): Structured Products Volume 2: Equity; Commoditiy; <strong>Credit</strong><br />

& New Markets. 3rd Edition Revised, John Wiley & Sons (Asia) Pte Ltd,<br />

Singapore.<br />

[DBR04] Deutsche B<strong>an</strong>k Research (2004): Kreditderivate: Wirkung auf die Sta-<br />

bilität der Fin<strong>an</strong>zmärkte. Deutsche B<strong>an</strong>k Research Economics Nr. 293, 1. April<br />

2004.<br />

[Deu97] Deutsche Bundesb<strong>an</strong>k (1997): <strong>Asset</strong>-Backed Securities in Deutschl<strong>an</strong>d: Die<br />

Veräusserung von Kreditforderungen durch deutsche Kreditinstitute. Deutsche<br />

Bundesb<strong>an</strong>k Monatsbericht Juli 1997, 57-67.<br />

[Deu04] Deutsche Bundesb<strong>an</strong>k (2004): Instrumente zum Kreditrisikotr<strong>an</strong>sfer: Ein-<br />

satz bei deutschen B<strong>an</strong>ken und Aspekte der Fin<strong>an</strong>zstabilität. Deutsche Bun-<br />

desb<strong>an</strong>k Monatsbericht April 2004, 27-45.<br />

[Deu04a] Deutsche Bundesb<strong>an</strong>k (2004): Neue Eigenkapital<strong>an</strong>forderungen für Kredi-<br />

tistitute (B<strong>as</strong>el II). Deutsche Bundesb<strong>an</strong>k Monatsbericht September 2004, 75-<br />

100.<br />

[Deu04b] Deutsche Bundesb<strong>an</strong>k (2004): <strong>Credit</strong> Default Swaps – Funktionen, Bedeu-<br />

tung und Informationsgehalt. Deutsche Bundesb<strong>an</strong>k Monatsbericht Dezember<br />

2004, 43-58.<br />

[Dor02] Dorfleitner, G. (2002): Stetige versus diskrete Renditen, Überlegungen zur<br />

richtigen Verwendung beider Begriffe in Theorie und Praxis. Kredit und Kapital<br />

2002(2), 216 − 241.<br />

[DS03] Duffie, D. Singleton K.J. (2003): <strong>Credit</strong> Risk – Pricing, Me<strong>as</strong>urement <strong>an</strong>d<br />

M<strong>an</strong>agement. Princeton University Press, New Jersey.<br />

[Dow05] DowJones Indexes (2005): Guide to the Dow Jones CDX Indexes. September<br />

2005.<br />

[Fit04] FitchRatings (2004): Global <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives Survey: Single-Name CDS<br />

Fuel Growth. FitchRatings <strong>Credit</strong> Policy 7 September 2004.<br />

[Fit04a] FitchRatings (2004): CDS Market Liquidity: Show Me the Money. FitchRat-<br />

ings Corporate Fin<strong>an</strong>ce 15 November 2004.<br />

[Fit05] FitchRatings (2005): Global <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives Survey: Risk Dispersion Ac-<br />

celerates. FitchRatings Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Institutions 17 November 2005.<br />

[Eur06] Europe<strong>an</strong> Securitisation Forum (2006): ESF Securitisation – Data Re-<br />

port. Winter 2006.<br />

[Gie04] Giesecke, K. (2004): <strong>Credit</strong> Risk Modeling <strong>an</strong>d Valuation: An Introduction.<br />

In: <strong>Credit</strong> Risk: Models <strong>an</strong>d M<strong>an</strong>agement, Vol. 2. D. Shimko (Editor), Risk-<br />

books, London.<br />

[Gre03] Greene, W.H. (2003): Econometric Analysis. Fifth Edition, Prentice Hall.<br />

190


BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />

[Gre98] Greensp<strong>an</strong>, A. (1998): The Role of Capital in Optimal B<strong>an</strong>king Supervision<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Regulation. FRBNY Economic Policy Reviw October 1998, 163-168.<br />

[Gre05] Greensp<strong>an</strong>, A. (2005): Risk tr<strong>an</strong>sfer <strong>an</strong>d fin<strong>an</strong>cial stability. BIS Review<br />

32/2005 5 May 2005.<br />

[GP95] Grill, W., Percynski, H. (1995): Wirtschaftslehre des Kreditwesens. 29.<br />

überarbeitete Auflage, Verlag Dr. Max Gehlen, Bad Homburg vor der Hoehe.<br />

[HLLM03] Harvey, C.R., Liechty, J.C., Liechty, M.W., Mueller, P. (2003):<br />

Portfolio Selection with Higher Moments. Working Paper.<br />

[Har95] Hartung, J. (1995): Statistik. 10. Auflage, R. Oldenburg Verlag, <strong>München</strong><br />

Wien.<br />

[Hul06] Hull, J. C. (2006): Options, Futures <strong>an</strong>d Other Derivatives. 6 th Edition,<br />

Prentice-Hall.<br />

[HW04] Hull, J., White, A. (2004): Valuation of a CDO <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> n th to Default CDS<br />

without Monte Carlo Simulation. The Journal of Derivatives XX, XX-XX.<br />

[Int06] International Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Services (2006): Securitisation. City Business<br />

Series March 2006.<br />

[Itr06a] iTraxx indices (2006): iTraxx Europe CDS Indices – Series 6. Presentation<br />

September 2006.<br />

[Itr06b] iTraxx indices (2006): iTraxx Europe Index Family – Index Rules. September<br />

2006.<br />

[JPM99] J.P. Morg<strong>an</strong> (1999): The J.P.Morg<strong>an</strong> guide to credit derivatives. J.P. Morg<strong>an</strong><br />

1999.<br />

[Kal60] Kalm<strong>an</strong>, R.E. (1960): A New Approach to Linear Filtering <strong>an</strong>d Prediction<br />

Problems. Journal of B<strong>as</strong>ic Engineering, Tr<strong>an</strong>sactions ASME Series D 83.<br />

[KSW05] Kalem<strong>an</strong>ova, A., Schmid, B., Werner, R. (2005): The Normal inverse<br />

Gaussi<strong>an</strong> distribution for sythetic CDO pricing. Working Paper.<br />

[KSG03] Kazemi, H. Schneeweis, T., Gupta, R. (2003): Omega <strong>as</strong> a Perform<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

Me<strong>as</strong>ure. Working Paper.<br />

[Kre02] Krengel, U. (2002): Einführung in die Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie und Sta-<br />

tistk. 6. Auflage, Vieweg, Braunschweig/Wiesbaden.<br />

[Leh06] Lehm<strong>an</strong> Brothers (2006): A Guide to the Lehm<strong>an</strong> Brothers Global Family<br />

of Indices. Fixed Income Research March 2006.<br />

[Mar52] Markowitz, H. (1952): Portfolio Selection. Journal of Fin<strong>an</strong>ce 7, 77-91.<br />

[Mey05] Meyer, T. (2005): Integrierte Modellierung von Zins- und Aktienmärkten.<br />

Diploma Thesis, TU Munich.<br />

191


BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />

[NS87] Nelson, C.R., Siegel, A.F. (1987): Parsimonious Modelling of Yield Curves.<br />

The Journal of Business 60(4), 473-489.<br />

[Nor98] Noris, J. (1998): Markov Chains. Cambridge Series in Statistical <strong>an</strong>d Proba-<br />

bilistic Mathematics; Cambridge University Press.<br />

[Oes04] Oesterreichische Nationalb<strong>an</strong>k (2004): Best Practice im Risikom<strong>an</strong>age-<br />

ment von Verbriefungen. Leitfadenreihe zum Kreditrisiko.<br />

[SZA06] Schmid, B., Zagst, R., Antes, S. (2006): Pricing of <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives.<br />

Working Paper.<br />

[SZAI06] Schmid, B., Zagst, R., Antes, S., Ilg, M. (2006): Empirical Evaluation of<br />

Hybrid Defaultable Bond Pricing Models. Working Paper.<br />

[Sch03] Schoenbucher, P.J. (2003): <strong>Credit</strong> Derivatives Pricing Models - Models,<br />

Pricing <strong>an</strong>d Implementation. John Wiley & Sons Ltd., Chichester.<br />

[SK02] Shadwick, W.F., Keating, C. (2002): A Universal Perform<strong>an</strong>ce Me<strong>as</strong>ure.<br />

Working Paper.<br />

[Sta02] St<strong>an</strong>dard & Poor’s (2002): Global C<strong>as</strong>h Flow <strong>an</strong>d Synthetic CDO Criteria.<br />

St<strong>an</strong>dard & Poor’s Structured Fin<strong>an</strong>ce March 2002.<br />

[Sta06] St<strong>an</strong>dard & Poor’s (2006): Annual 2005 Global Corporate Default Study<br />

And Rating Tr<strong>an</strong>sitions. St<strong>an</strong>dard & Poor’s Global Fixed Income Research J<strong>an</strong>-<br />

uary 2006.<br />

[SB00] Steiner, M., Bruns, C. (2000): Wertpapierm<strong>an</strong>agement. 7., überarbeitete<br />

und erweiterte Auflage, Schaeffer-Poeschel Verlag, Stuttgart.<br />

[Tem05] Tempes, M. (2005): Implementierung einer Copula-Toolbox unter Matlab.<br />

Diploma Thesis, TU Munich.<br />

[V<strong>as</strong>87] V<strong>as</strong>icek, O. (1987): Probability of Loss on Lo<strong>an</strong> Portfolio. KMV corporation<br />

August 1987.<br />

[Zag02] Zagst, R. (2002): Interest Rate M<strong>an</strong>agement. Springer-Verlag, Berlin, Heidel-<br />

berg, New York.<br />

[Zag03] Zagst, R. (2003): Lecture Notes: Portfolio Theory <strong>an</strong>d <strong>Asset</strong> Pricing. TU<br />

Munich.<br />

[Zag06] Zagst, R. (2006): Lecture Notes: Integrated Risk M<strong>an</strong>agement – Distinguished<br />

Lecure Series 2006. TU Munich.<br />

[ZMH06] Zagst, R., Meyer, T., Hagedorn, H. (2006): Integrated Modelling of Stock<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Bond Markets. Working Paper.<br />

[Zhu04] Zhu, H. (2004): An empirical comparison of credit spreads between the bond<br />

market <strong>an</strong>d the credit default swap market. BIS Working Papers No 160.<br />

192

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!