13.06.2014 Views

Technical University Munich Commodities as an Asset Class - risklab

Technical University Munich Commodities as an Asset Class - risklab

Technical University Munich Commodities as an Asset Class - risklab

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Technical</strong> <strong>University</strong> <strong>Munich</strong><br />

Department of Fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

Mathematics<br />

<strong>Commodities</strong> <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> <strong>Asset</strong> Cl<strong>as</strong>s<br />

Diploma Thesis<br />

by<br />

Maria Katharina Heiden<br />

Referent: Prof. Dr. Rudi Zagst<br />

Co-Referent: Dr. Reinhold Hafner<br />

Closing Date: 06.12.2006


This work is dedicated to my parents who always supported me: On my long way<br />

during the study of Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Mathematics they remained steadf<strong>as</strong>tly at my side<br />

<strong>an</strong>d gave good advice. I’m very lucky to have parents like them.<br />

I declare that I wrote this diploma thesis by my own <strong>an</strong>d that I only used the mentioned<br />

sources.<br />

<strong>Munich</strong>, 06.12.2006<br />

ii


Acknowledgements<br />

First <strong>an</strong>d foremost, I would like to th<strong>an</strong>k my academic teacher Prof. Dr. Rudi<br />

Zagst from whom I have learned what I know about fin<strong>an</strong>cial mathematics. His<br />

great fin<strong>an</strong>ce lectures have boosted my interest in economics <strong>an</strong>d fin<strong>an</strong>ce during my<br />

studies. Moreover, his engagement to improve teaching <strong>an</strong>d fit it to students needs,<br />

have forced myself to work hard <strong>an</strong>d show him my th<strong>an</strong>ks with good results.<br />

I would like to express my sincere th<strong>an</strong>ks for his advice <strong>an</strong>d guid<strong>an</strong>ce to Dr. Reinhold<br />

Hafner. He agreed to be my thesis advisor at <strong>risklab</strong> Germ<strong>an</strong>y GmbH <strong>an</strong>d gave<br />

me the ch<strong>an</strong>ce to write about this great topic. His way to show me the link between<br />

theory <strong>an</strong>d praxis w<strong>as</strong> a key ingredient for my success <strong>an</strong>d joy during my diploma<br />

time.<br />

Moreover, th<strong>an</strong>ks to my colleague Dr. Wolfg<strong>an</strong>g Mader who opened my horizon for<br />

statistics in challenging discussions.<br />

L<strong>as</strong>t but not le<strong>as</strong>t, I would like to th<strong>an</strong>k Mr. Nichol<strong>as</strong> Drude, the best fellow<br />

student someone c<strong>an</strong> imagine. I appreciate his patience in endless mathematical,<br />

philosophical <strong>an</strong>d sometimes unsubst<strong>an</strong>tial discussions.<br />

iii


Contents<br />

1 Introduction 1<br />

2 Overview of Commodity Markets 4<br />

2.1 The different Commodity Types . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5<br />

2.1.1 Energy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7<br />

2.1.1.1 Crude Oil . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7<br />

2.1.1.2 Natural G<strong>as</strong> . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12<br />

2.1.2 Metals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15<br />

2.1.2.1 Precious Metals exemplified by Gold . . . . . . . . . 16<br />

2.1.2.2 Industrial Metals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19<br />

2.1.3 Agricultures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21<br />

2.1.3.1 Softs exemplified by Cocoa . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23<br />

2.1.3.2 Grains exemplified by Corn . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25<br />

2.1.3.3 Livestock exemplified by Live <strong>an</strong>d Feeder Cattle . . . 26<br />

2.2 Characteristics of Commodity Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28<br />

2.3 Trading <strong>Commodities</strong> . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31<br />

2.3.1 Commodity Derivatives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32<br />

2.3.1.1 Forwards <strong>an</strong>d Futures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33<br />

2.3.1.2 Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35<br />

2.3.1.3 Swaps . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37<br />

2.3.1.4 Commodity Linked Structured Notes . . . . . . . . . 38<br />

2.3.1.5 Certificates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39<br />

2.3.2 M<strong>an</strong>aged Futures Funds . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39<br />

2.3.3 Stocks of Commodity Producing Comp<strong>an</strong>ies . . . . . . . . . . 41<br />

3 Pricing of Commodity Futures 44<br />

3.1 The Risk Premium Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45<br />

3.2 The Convenience Yield Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50<br />

3.3 Relationship of the Risk Premium <strong>an</strong>d Convenience Yield Model . . . 53<br />

3.4 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55<br />

3.4.1 One Factor Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56<br />

3.4.2 Two Factor Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63<br />

3.4.3 Three Factor Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70<br />

4 Commodity Indices 73<br />

4.1 Characteristics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74<br />

v


Contents<br />

4.1.1 Index Composition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74<br />

4.1.2 Index Weights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74<br />

4.1.3 Rebal<strong>an</strong>cing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75<br />

4.1.4 Return Calculation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75<br />

4.1.5 Leveraged versus unleveraged Returns . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75<br />

4.2 The Major Market Indices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75<br />

4.2.1 CRB . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76<br />

4.2.2 GSCI . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77<br />

4.2.3 DJ-AIGCI . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78<br />

4.2.4 DBLCI . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79<br />

4.2.5 DBLCI-MR . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79<br />

4.2.6 RICI . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81<br />

4.2.7 Comparison of the Major Market Indices . . . . . . . . . . . . 81<br />

4.3 Index Linked Products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83<br />

4.3.1 Derivatives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83<br />

4.3.2 Mutual Funds . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84<br />

4.3.3 Exch<strong>an</strong>ge Traded Funds . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86<br />

4.4 Decomposition of Index Returns . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88<br />

5 Properties of Commodity Returns 94<br />

5.1 Characteristics of Single <strong>Commodities</strong> . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95<br />

5.1.1 Risk <strong>an</strong>d Return Profile . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96<br />

5.1.2 Correlation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 102<br />

5.1.3 Diversification . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110<br />

5.2 Properties of the DJ-AIGCI Return Components . . . . . . . . . . . 116<br />

5.2.1 Key Statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117<br />

5.2.2 Roll Returns . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 120<br />

5.2.3 Distribution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 123<br />

5.2.4 Stationarity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132<br />

5.2.5 Autocorrelation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 135<br />

6 <strong>Asset</strong> Allocation with Commodity Derivatives 140<br />

6.1 Me<strong>an</strong> Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Sp<strong>an</strong>ning . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140<br />

6.2 Dependence to Stocks, Bonds <strong>an</strong>d Inflation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 144<br />

6.3 Portfolio Optimization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 148<br />

7 Conclusions 157<br />

A Data Description 160<br />

vi


Contents<br />

B Characteristics of Selected <strong>Commodities</strong> 164<br />

B.1 Heating Oil . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 164<br />

B.2 G<strong>as</strong>oline . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 166<br />

B.3 Gold . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 167<br />

B.4 Aluminium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 169<br />

B.5 Copper . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 170<br />

B.6 Lead . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 171<br />

B.7 Nickel . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173<br />

B.8 Zinc . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 174<br />

B.9 Sugar . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 175<br />

B.10 Coffee . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 177<br />

B.11 Soybe<strong>an</strong> Complex . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 178<br />

B.12 Le<strong>an</strong> Hogs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 181<br />

C Mathematical Preliminaries 183<br />

C.1 Statistical B<strong>as</strong>ics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 183<br />

C.2 Probability Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 190<br />

C.3 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Differential Equations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 193<br />

C.4 Equivalent Me<strong>as</strong>ure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 195<br />

C.5 Feynm<strong>an</strong>-Kac Representation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 197<br />

D Program Codes 199<br />

D.1 Portfolio Allocation with <strong>Commodities</strong> . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 199<br />

D.2 Hurdle Rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 201<br />

D.3 Help Function . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 205<br />

References 208<br />

vii


List of Figures<br />

2.1 Overview of the different Commodity Types . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6<br />

2.2 Crude Oil Historical Price Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8<br />

2.3 Crude Oil Reserves . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10<br />

2.4 Net Crude Oil Consumption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11<br />

2.5 Natural G<strong>as</strong> Price <strong>an</strong>d Net Consumption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13<br />

2.6 Natural G<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong>d Crude Oil Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14<br />

2.7 Gold Price Movements between 1960-2006 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17<br />

2.8 Today’s Gold Price Dependence of the US dollar . . . . . . . . . . . . 18<br />

2.9 The London Metals Exch<strong>an</strong>ge Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20<br />

2.10 Cocoa Be<strong>an</strong> Price . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23<br />

2.11 Cocoa Be<strong>an</strong> Price <strong>an</strong>d Net Consumption Ch<strong>an</strong>ge . . . . . . . . . . . 24<br />

2.12 Corn Price, Stock of Inventory, Production <strong>an</strong>d Consumption . . . . . 26<br />

2.13 Cattle Price, Stock of Inventory, Production <strong>an</strong>d Consumption . . . . 27<br />

2.14 Dependency of Feeder Cattle <strong>an</strong>d Corn Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28<br />

2.15 Commodity Markets Process Chain . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29<br />

2.16 Overview of Commodity Investment Instruments . . . . . . . . . . . . 32<br />

2.17 Commodity Swap Payment Streams . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37<br />

2.18 Commodity Linked Structured Notes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38<br />

2.19 Comparison of Gold <strong>an</strong>d Gold Mining Comp<strong>an</strong>ies . . . . . . . . . . . 42<br />

3.1 The Risk Premium Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46<br />

3.2 Backwardation <strong>an</strong>d Cont<strong>an</strong>go . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47<br />

3.3 The Concept of Expectational Vari<strong>an</strong>ce . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50<br />

4.1 The CRB Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76<br />

4.2 The GSCI Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78<br />

4.3 The DJ-AIGCI Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79<br />

4.4 The DBLCI Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80<br />

4.5 The DBLCI-MR Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80<br />

4.6 The RICI Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81<br />

4.7 Index Component Distribution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83<br />

4.8 Decomposition of Commodity Index Return . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88<br />

4.9 Term Structure of NYMEX Crude Oil <strong>as</strong> per July 2006 . . . . . . . . 93<br />

5.1 Relationship between Backwardation <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>nualized Return . . . . . 98<br />

5.2 Diversification between single commodity groups . . . . . . . . . . . . 104<br />

5.3 Linear Correlation within <strong>an</strong>d between Commodity Groups (1998-2006)107<br />

5.4 Dependence of Market Index (1998-2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110<br />

5.5 Diversification among commodity groups . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 112<br />

ix


List of Figures<br />

5.6 Factor Analysis (1991-2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116<br />

5.7 Perform<strong>an</strong>ce of DJ-AIGCI Components . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118<br />

5.8 Return Behavior of DJ-AIGCI Components . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119<br />

5.9 Perform<strong>an</strong>ce of DJ-AIGCI Roll Returns . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121<br />

5.10 Time the DJ-AIGCI spent in Cont<strong>an</strong>go or in Backwardation . . . . . 121<br />

5.11 Distribution Ch<strong>an</strong>ge . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 122<br />

5.12 Histogram with Norm-Fit of DJ-AIGCI Return Components . . . . . 124<br />

5.13 Kernel Distribution with Norm-Fit of DJ-AIGCI Return Components 131<br />

5.14 Lagged Plot of DJ-AIGCI Return Components . . . . . . . . . . . . . 136<br />

5.15 Autocorrelation <strong>an</strong>d Partial Autocorrelation Function of DJ-AIGCI<br />

Return Components . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 137<br />

6.1 Factor Analysis with other <strong>Asset</strong> Cl<strong>as</strong>ses (1991-2006) . . . . . . . . . 143<br />

6.2 Perform<strong>an</strong>ce of different <strong>Asset</strong> Cl<strong>as</strong>ses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 144<br />

6.3 Efficient Frontiers with <strong>an</strong>d without <strong>Commodities</strong> (1991-2006) . . . . 154<br />

6.4 Comparison of Portfolio Allocation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 155<br />

6.5 Efficient Frontier <strong>an</strong>d the Hurdle Rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 156<br />

B.1 Dependence of Heating Oil Prices to Crude Oil Prices . . . . . . . . . 164<br />

B.2 Heating Oil Prices for Future Delivery . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165<br />

B.3 Dependence of G<strong>as</strong>oline Prices on Crude Oil Prices . . . . . . . . . . 166<br />

B.4 Gold Inventories <strong>an</strong>d Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 168<br />

B.5 Aluminium Inventories <strong>an</strong>d Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 169<br />

B.6 Copper Inventories <strong>an</strong>d Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 171<br />

B.7 Lead Inventories <strong>an</strong>d Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 172<br />

B.8 Nickel Inventories <strong>an</strong>d Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173<br />

B.9 Zinc Inventories <strong>an</strong>d Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 175<br />

B.10 Sugar Price, Stock of Inventory, Production <strong>an</strong>d Consumption . . . . 176<br />

B.11 Coffee Price . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 177<br />

B.12 Coffee Price <strong>an</strong>d Stock of Inventory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 178<br />

B.13 Soybe<strong>an</strong> Price, Stock of Inventory, Production <strong>an</strong>d Consumption . . . 181<br />

B.14 Le<strong>an</strong> Hogs Price, Stock of Inventory, Production <strong>an</strong>d Consumption . 182<br />

x


List of Tables<br />

2.1 Oil Reserves <strong>an</strong>d Production . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10<br />

3.1 Equivalent Parameters . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68<br />

4.1 Comparison of Commodity Index Characteristics . . . . . . . . . . . 82<br />

4.2 Commodity Index linked Mutual Funds . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85<br />

4.3 Construction of a Futures Return Series for Crude Oil . . . . . . . . . 89<br />

4.4 Spot, Future <strong>an</strong>d Roll Return Time Series for Crude Oil . . . . . . . 91<br />

4.5 Construction of a Futures Return Series for Copper . . . . . . . . . . 92<br />

4.6 Spot, Future <strong>an</strong>d Roll Return Time Series for Copper . . . . . . . . . 92<br />

5.1 Return Components of different Commodity Indices (1998-2006) . . . 97<br />

5.2 Volatility Components of different Commodity Indices (1998-2006) . . 101<br />

5.3 Pearson Correlation (1998-2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104<br />

5.4 Kendall Correlation (1998-2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106<br />

5.5 Key Statistics of DJ-AIGCI Components . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119<br />

5.6 Key Statistics of DJ-AIGCI Roll Return . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 123<br />

5.7 Distribution Statistics of DJ-AIGCI Return Components . . . . . . . 126<br />

5.8 Signific<strong>an</strong>ce Tests for Normality of DJ-AIGCI Total Return . . . . . . 130<br />

5.9 Dickey Fuller Test for Stationarity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 135<br />

5.10 Signific<strong>an</strong>ce Tests for Autocorrelation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 138<br />

6.1 Me<strong>an</strong> Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Sp<strong>an</strong>ning Coefficients (1991-2006) . . . . . . . . . . . 142<br />

6.2 Me<strong>an</strong> Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Sp<strong>an</strong>ning Coefficients (2002-2006) . . . . . . . . . . . 142<br />

6.3 Key Statistics of different <strong>Asset</strong> Cl<strong>as</strong>ses’ Returns (1991-2006) . . . . . 145<br />

6.4 Kendall/Pearson Correlation between Different <strong>Asset</strong> Cl<strong>as</strong>ses <strong>an</strong>d Inflation<br />

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 146<br />

6.5 Pearson Correlation between average Return <strong>an</strong>d Volatility . . . . . . 147<br />

xi


1 Introduction<br />

Investing in fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>sets w<strong>as</strong> for a long time <strong>an</strong> exclusive <strong>an</strong>d covered business<br />

which w<strong>as</strong> reserved to institutional <strong>an</strong>d selected wealthy investors. The introduction<br />

of the internet <strong>an</strong>d direct brokerage made tr<strong>an</strong>saction costs falling <strong>an</strong>d hence<br />

investment became available to the broad public. While the investment volume in<br />

stock <strong>an</strong>d bond markets grew steadily in America over the l<strong>as</strong>t 20 <strong>an</strong>d in Europe<br />

over the l<strong>as</strong>t 10 years,, commodities did not play a major role in fin<strong>an</strong>cial investment<br />

owing their low prices <strong>an</strong>d in-tr<strong>an</strong>sparency. But the situation h<strong>as</strong> ch<strong>an</strong>ged over the<br />

p<strong>as</strong>t 5 years. Industry h<strong>as</strong> grown to close to 9 billion traded contracts in 2005. 1<br />

Due to low perform<strong>an</strong>ce of stocks <strong>an</strong>d bonds, the time period from 2000 to 2003<br />

boosted the growth of fin<strong>an</strong>cial commodity markets in particular. The total amount<br />

of traded contracts h<strong>as</strong> nearly tripled during this time. There are two dimensions<br />

which foster the development: hedging <strong>an</strong>d investing. The former is mainly driven<br />

by structural ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the global economy <strong>an</strong>d the remarkable dem<strong>an</strong>d during the<br />

1980s <strong>an</strong>d 1990s: Certain industries lowered their resource intensity noticeably or<br />

became more efficient. This applies for inst<strong>an</strong>ce to the automobile industry which<br />

h<strong>as</strong> steadily reduced the proportion of metal in their cars. Something similar c<strong>an</strong><br />

also be noted for farm outputs which could be incre<strong>as</strong>ed considerably by me<strong>an</strong>s of<br />

technological improvements. For this re<strong>as</strong>on, producing commodities became a less<br />

attractive <strong>an</strong>d low profit business. This development led, however, to a decre<strong>as</strong>e in<br />

production <strong>an</strong>d falling inventories. After the collapse of the communist system, approximately<br />

three billion people, accounting for almost 70% of world’s population,<br />

entered into global trade. Their cheap labor costs attracted low educational work of<br />

the producing business or IT-services of international acting comp<strong>an</strong>ies. This way<br />

of proceeding boosted their economic growth <strong>an</strong>d hence the need for more energy,<br />

new infr<strong>as</strong>tructure, diversified food <strong>an</strong>d thus, for commodities. Caused by the recession<br />

in the commodity producing industry during the 1980s, the business w<strong>as</strong> not<br />

prepared for the sudden dem<strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>d prices went through the roof. This forced comp<strong>an</strong>ies<br />

to focus on commodity price risk m<strong>an</strong>agement what fuelled the dem<strong>an</strong>d for<br />

fin<strong>an</strong>cial risk hedging products. On the other h<strong>an</strong>d, the low perform<strong>an</strong>ce of stocks<br />

<strong>an</strong>d bonds between 2000 <strong>an</strong>d 2003 moved investors to look around for new, more<br />

attractive return sources. Rising prices of commodities since 2001, have stimulated<br />

their interest <strong>an</strong>d thereupon, the dem<strong>an</strong>d for products to enable investment in this<br />

market.<br />

On the following pages, we introduce commodity markets from the investment’s<br />

1 See Futures Industry Magazine J<strong>an</strong>/Feb 2006, Figure includes contracts on fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>sets.<br />

1


1 Introduction<br />

point of view i.e. commodities are highlighted <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s. The starting shoot<br />

is in Section 2 <strong>an</strong> ”Overview of Commodity Markets”. First, we look closer into the<br />

three commodity groups <strong>as</strong> there are: energy, metals <strong>an</strong>d agriculture. Energy is one<br />

of the most import<strong>an</strong>t goods in our daily life. It h<strong>as</strong> a signific<strong>an</strong>t economic impact<br />

on all other commodity groups. Afterwards, we give a brief overview of market<br />

particip<strong>an</strong>ts, their motivation <strong>an</strong>d relev<strong>an</strong>t commodity market characteristics. The<br />

section concludes with a rough outline on commodity trading vehicles<br />

In Section 3 ”Pricing of Commodity Futures” we embody the characteristics of<br />

commodity prices into mathematical forms. Although the underlying trading vehicle<br />

for commodities are futures contracts, i.e. fin<strong>an</strong>cial derivatives, their price c<strong>an</strong>not be<br />

valued following general arbitrage arguments. <strong>Commodities</strong> are <strong>as</strong>sumption goods<br />

<strong>an</strong>d therefore, it is possible that inventories are eaten up in times of scarcity yielding<br />

into the impossibility to create a hedging portfolio that gives the fair price of the<br />

fin<strong>an</strong>cial derivative. Moreover, the price of commodities is driven by supply <strong>an</strong>d<br />

dem<strong>an</strong>d. This h<strong>as</strong> to be taken into consideration.<br />

Lectures 2 about stock markets show that investors are attracted to broad diversified<br />

exposure in the selected <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s. This is represented by indices which<br />

we introduce in Section 4 ”Commodity Indices”. Moreover, we discuss their common<br />

properties <strong>an</strong>d single characteristics. It might be surprising that the market is<br />

strongly dominated by two indices offered by Goldm<strong>an</strong> Sachs <strong>an</strong>d Dow Jones <strong>an</strong>d<br />

that the different commodity indices generally are not older th<strong>an</strong> five to ten years.<br />

This is re<strong>as</strong>oned by the adolescence of the market. In the l<strong>as</strong>t part of the section<br />

we decompose the index return into its single elements: spot, roll <strong>an</strong>d interest rate<br />

return earned on collateral.<br />

In Section 5 the statistical ”Properties of Commodity Returns” is addressed. The<br />

first part aims to show that the returns of the different single commodities interact<br />

homogenously among each other within the three commodity groups energy, metals<br />

<strong>an</strong>d agricultures but heterogeneously between them. Therefore, <strong>an</strong> investor c<strong>an</strong> gain<br />

extra profit by diversifying its exposure among the different commodity groups.<br />

Nevertheless, it comes up that the economic signific<strong>an</strong>ce of oil <strong>an</strong>d oil products<br />

at first seen in Section 2 c<strong>an</strong> also be seen statistically in index returns that are<br />

composed out of different commodity groups. We identify the Dow Jones Index<br />

<strong>as</strong> bal<strong>an</strong>ced commodity exposure <strong>an</strong>d the second part of Section 5 gives a deeper<br />

insight into distribution properties of the single elements of the index. It comes up,<br />

that roll returns had a huge impact on the total value gain of the index.<br />

2 For inst<strong>an</strong>ce [Campbell 2000].<br />

2


Finally, we bring commodity returns into the portfolio context. In Section 6 ”Strategic<br />

<strong>Asset</strong> Allocation with Commodity Derivatives” we show that commodity investments,<br />

represented by the Dow Jones AIG Commodity Index, are indeed <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set<br />

cl<strong>as</strong>s of its own. Furthermore, we present the cross relations of commodity returns<br />

to stock <strong>an</strong>d bond returns <strong>an</strong>d show that slightly negative correlation characteristics<br />

yield to a better risk <strong>an</strong>d return profile of portfolios including stocks, bonds<br />

<strong>an</strong>d commodities in comparison to traditional portfolios including stocks <strong>an</strong>d bonds<br />

only. It is a major conclusion that the better risk <strong>an</strong>d return profile is independent<br />

of the <strong>as</strong>sumption of extraordinary high commodity returns like the ones realized<br />

over the l<strong>as</strong>t years.<br />

3


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

After the wall came down <strong>an</strong>d the communist system broke down, emerging countries<br />

have economically grown much f<strong>as</strong>ter th<strong>an</strong> industrial countries. The integration<br />

of global fin<strong>an</strong>cial markets, the exp<strong>an</strong>sion of international comp<strong>an</strong>ies by outsourcing<br />

their production into low labor cost countries <strong>an</strong>d the liberalization of trade<br />

restrictions had a positive impact to the economies of the emerging markets. For<br />

inst<strong>an</strong>ce, China’s share of global Growth Domestic Product (GDP) incre<strong>as</strong>ed from<br />

6% in 1990 to 15% in 2005 drawing level with the Euro zone. India’s share of global<br />

GDP incre<strong>as</strong>ed from 4.25% in 1990 after all to 6% in 2005 drawing level with Jap<strong>an</strong>. 3<br />

Additionally, the commodity import <strong>an</strong>d export rates incre<strong>as</strong>ed by two re<strong>as</strong>ons. On<br />

the one h<strong>an</strong>d, the commodity dem<strong>an</strong>d of the emerging countries is a function of<br />

the final good dem<strong>an</strong>d of the industrial countries. On the other h<strong>an</strong>d, commodities<br />

are needed to push industrialization <strong>an</strong>d electrification, urb<strong>an</strong>ization <strong>an</strong>d exp<strong>an</strong>sion<br />

of the road networks. Because global commodity supply w<strong>as</strong> regressive during the<br />

1980s <strong>an</strong>d 1990s, the business didn’t invest into new production are<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong>d reduced<br />

production to stable prices. As, at the beginning of the 21rst century, the internal<br />

dem<strong>an</strong>d of emerging countries for commodities incre<strong>as</strong>ed sharply, the business w<strong>as</strong><br />

not prepared resulting into short term supply shortages <strong>an</strong>d a strong commodity<br />

price incre<strong>as</strong>e.<br />

At the moment we are in the middle of the fourth price rally of the l<strong>as</strong>t 100 years.<br />

The first two were caused by the two world wars which were followed by global<br />

economic break downs <strong>an</strong>d the third occurred during the 1970th <strong>as</strong> the US started<br />

to print money to fin<strong>an</strong>ce its Vietnam War yielding into a hyper inflation period.<br />

Inflation is me<strong>as</strong>ured <strong>as</strong> the ch<strong>an</strong>ge of a product b<strong>as</strong>ket’s value. But products are<br />

made of commodities explaining the brotherhood of inflation <strong>an</strong>d commodity prices.<br />

The price surge w<strong>as</strong> supported by oil supply bottle necks caused by a loss of Ir<strong>an</strong><br />

<strong>as</strong> a major oil supplier. The current high price environment in commodity markets<br />

are not driven by high inflation. The major re<strong>as</strong>on is that the supply <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d<br />

equilibrium collapsed.<br />

An additional side effect causing commodity prices to rise h<strong>as</strong> been the depreciating<br />

value of the US dollar, i.e. the value of the dollar in terms of <strong>an</strong>other currency, e.g.<br />

the Euro or the Yen, decre<strong>as</strong>ed over the l<strong>as</strong>t years. The exch<strong>an</strong>ge rate is defined<br />

<strong>as</strong> the price of one currency in terms of <strong>an</strong>other currency or more pl<strong>as</strong>tic spoken:<br />

The exch<strong>an</strong>ge rate adjusts the price of a good in one country to be the same in<br />

3 See [UBS research 2006].<br />

4


2.1 The different Commodity Types<br />

terms of <strong>an</strong>other countries currency. 4 Exch<strong>an</strong>ge rates are determined by incomes<br />

<strong>an</strong>d relative prices. <strong>Commodities</strong>, <strong>as</strong> real <strong>as</strong>sets, typically rise in price when the<br />

currency in which they are quoted depreciates in value <strong>an</strong>d although commodity<br />

markets grow globally, the main trading currency is still the US dollar. The US<br />

government h<strong>as</strong> built up a m<strong>as</strong>sive account deficit which is caused by imports outweighting<br />

exports. Higher imports th<strong>an</strong> exports cause <strong>an</strong> over supply in US dollar<br />

<strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> over dem<strong>an</strong>d of foreign currency what weakens the value of the US dollar<br />

<strong>an</strong>d rises commodity prices.<br />

The introductory words uncover the major characteristics in commodity markets.<br />

The prices are driven by current <strong>an</strong>d expected future supply <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d equilibriums.<br />

In Section 2.1 we will give a more detailed inside into the three major<br />

commodity groups energy, metals <strong>an</strong>d agricultures. It will become clear that the<br />

single elements of the groups follow their own risk factors although technological<br />

improvements enable substitutions. Because our main purpose is the <strong>an</strong>alysis of investable<br />

commodities we only include commodities that are traded at <strong>an</strong> exch<strong>an</strong>ge.<br />

When it comes to commodity investment, we need to underst<strong>an</strong>d the interaction of<br />

the different market particip<strong>an</strong>ts <strong>an</strong>d their trading motivations. This is discussed in<br />

Section 2.2. We close the overview of commodity markets with a brief summary of<br />

the different fin<strong>an</strong>cial vehicles enabling commodity investments in Section 2.3.<br />

2.1 The different Commodity Types<br />

Commodity markets are divided into three major groups: energy, metals <strong>an</strong>d agricultures<br />

<strong>as</strong> it c<strong>an</strong> be seen in Figure 2.1. Into the energy group account all products<br />

which c<strong>an</strong> be used to produce electricity, heat <strong>an</strong>d fuel. While coal drove the industrialization<br />

through the 18th <strong>an</strong>d 19th century, the commodity w<strong>as</strong> substituted by<br />

oil since the beginning of the l<strong>as</strong>t century. Today’s high price environment drives a<br />

new substitution wave into alternative energy sources. Because crude oil <strong>an</strong>d natural<br />

g<strong>as</strong> account for around 60% of word’s energy usage we will discuss them in<br />

Section 2.1.1 more detailed.<br />

Appendix B.1 <strong>an</strong>d B.2 will further give a detailed <strong>an</strong>alysis of crude oil downstream<br />

products heating oil <strong>an</strong>d g<strong>as</strong>oline. It is provided to get a deeper underst<strong>an</strong>ding of<br />

the use impact, oil h<strong>as</strong> to our daily life.<br />

4 See [Sawyer Sprinkle 2003].<br />

5


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

Figure 2.1: Overview of the different Commodity Types<br />

The second big commodity group are the metals which again c<strong>an</strong> be divided into the<br />

precious <strong>an</strong>d the industrial metals. Gold <strong>as</strong> a representative of the first mentioned<br />

sub group c<strong>an</strong>not be seen <strong>as</strong> a simple commodity used in jewelery <strong>an</strong>d <strong>as</strong> electric<br />

conductor but also include the role <strong>as</strong> a world currency. It is discussed in detail<br />

in the first paragraph of Section 2.1.2 <strong>an</strong>d we will see that although the historical<br />

backing of currencies with gold doesn’t exist <strong>an</strong>ymore, investors still see gold <strong>as</strong> a<br />

currency <strong>an</strong>d wealth storage yielding into a high negative correlation to US dollar<br />

value ch<strong>an</strong>ges. The second paragraph of Section 2.1.2 gives a brief introduction to<br />

the industrial metals business. The industry line went through a fundamental ch<strong>an</strong>ge<br />

yielding into a monopoly of some selected producers. In Appendix B.4 to B.8 c<strong>an</strong><br />

further be found some fundamental <strong>an</strong>alysis of the major metals used in construction<br />

<strong>an</strong>d building, including aluminium, copper, lead, nickel <strong>an</strong>d zinc. The sections show<br />

that a major dem<strong>an</strong>d went inventories down <strong>an</strong>d generally current investments in<br />

new mines <strong>an</strong>d refineries will yield fruits five to ten years later. Implicating, that<br />

prices will stay high over the near future.<br />

The third group <strong>as</strong> shown in Figure 2.1 are the agricultures. This group is by<br />

far the most heterogenous one. It is divided into the softs, the grains <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

livestock products. The major characteristic of these commodities is the se<strong>as</strong>onality<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the sensitivity to weather conditions <strong>an</strong>d epidemics. While metals <strong>an</strong>d energy<br />

already incre<strong>as</strong>ed in price sharply, agricultures are lacking behind. The <strong>an</strong>alysis in<br />

Section 2.1.3 will show that inventories are low <strong>an</strong>d new fields of application, e.g.<br />

alternative fuels, cause further dem<strong>an</strong>d.<br />

6


2.1 The different Commodity Types<br />

2.1.1 Energy<br />

Everybody’s daily life is unimaginable without energy. The first energy sources<br />

of men kind were wood, wind <strong>an</strong>d water. Especially wood w<strong>as</strong> used <strong>as</strong> a heating<br />

medium. Over the centuries it became scarce around cities <strong>an</strong>d people were forced to<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ge to <strong>an</strong>other heating source. Great Britain w<strong>as</strong> the first nation that switched<br />

to coal in the 17th century. With ongoing industrialization its usage incre<strong>as</strong>ed but<br />

with it environmental problems. Since the middle of the 19th century the next<br />

huge ch<strong>an</strong>ge started, the ch<strong>an</strong>ge from coal to oil. Especially the invention <strong>an</strong>d<br />

industrial integration of the combustion engine pushed world’s need for oil <strong>as</strong> major<br />

energy source. Nowadays, energy became besides fresh water <strong>an</strong>d cle<strong>an</strong> air the<br />

most import<strong>an</strong>t element in hum<strong>an</strong> life <strong>an</strong>d nobody c<strong>an</strong> imagine to live without<br />

electrical light, heating <strong>an</strong>d automatic tr<strong>an</strong>sportation. No wonder, that energy<br />

prices have a huge impact to our life <strong>an</strong>d therewith, to industry. During the l<strong>as</strong>t<br />

years, there h<strong>as</strong> been a huge oil price surge. The re<strong>as</strong>ons for this are m<strong>an</strong>ifold <strong>an</strong>d<br />

shall be explained in Section 2.1.1.1. Moreover, crude oil is the input for two also<br />

exch<strong>an</strong>ge traded downstream products: heating oil <strong>an</strong>d g<strong>as</strong>oline. Their dependence<br />

structure <strong>an</strong>d market characteristics are explained in Appendix B.1 <strong>an</strong>d B.2. The<br />

high price environment provoked by scarcity <strong>an</strong>d political instability put men kind<br />

under evolutionary pressure to ch<strong>an</strong>ge to <strong>an</strong>other major energy source. Because coal<br />

<strong>an</strong>d nuclear energy are, caused by their unattractive environmental impacts, only<br />

short term alternatives, natural g<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong>d so-called alternative energy sources <strong>as</strong> listed<br />

in Figure 2.1 are getting more popular. Natural g<strong>as</strong> is today the most promising<br />

alternative <strong>an</strong>d therefore, discussed in the Section 2.1.1.2.<br />

2.1.1.1 Crude Oil<br />

Crude oil is petroleum that is acquired directly from the ground. It is formed millions<br />

of years ago from the remains of tiny aquatic pl<strong>an</strong>ts <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>imals that lived in <strong>an</strong>cient<br />

se<strong>as</strong>. Around 4,000 BC in Mesopotamia a tarry crude oil, called bitumen, w<strong>as</strong> used<br />

<strong>as</strong> caulking for ships, <strong>as</strong> a setting for jewels <strong>an</strong>d mosaics. The walls of Babylon <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the Egypti<strong>an</strong> Pyramids are hold together with bitumen. During the 19th century<br />

in America, <strong>an</strong> oil finding w<strong>as</strong> often met with sadness, water w<strong>as</strong> more attractive.<br />

It w<strong>as</strong>n’t until 1854, with the invention of the oil lamp, that the first large-scale<br />

dem<strong>an</strong>d for petroleum emerged. Rockefeller became the first billionaire by giving<br />

away these lamps for free <strong>an</strong>d earning money by selling the kerosine. Today, crude<br />

oil is <strong>as</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t for the economy <strong>as</strong> air is import<strong>an</strong>t for men. It became world’s<br />

first trillion dollar industry <strong>an</strong>d accounts for the single largest product in world<br />

7


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

trade. The different kinds r<strong>an</strong>ge from light colorless liquids to black oily sledges <strong>an</strong>d<br />

are named by their origin. The most import<strong>an</strong>t kinds of crude oil are:<br />

Brent Blend: a mix of 15 different crude oils from the the North Sea<br />

West Tex<strong>as</strong> Intermediate (WTI) from the USA<br />

Dubai from the Middle E<strong>as</strong>t<br />

Tapis from Malaysia<br />

Min<strong>as</strong> from Indonesia<br />

Crude oil w<strong>as</strong> one of the hottest topics in the l<strong>as</strong>t years <strong>an</strong>d the market h<strong>as</strong> become<br />

the biggest <strong>an</strong>d most developed of all commodity markets. The development<br />

beg<strong>an</strong> in the 1970s <strong>as</strong> world’s industry realized its dependency of oil <strong>an</strong>d the need<br />

for hedging. In 2001 a new price surge started. In 1999 a barrel crude oil costed<br />

around 10 US dollar <strong>an</strong>d now in 2006 it is quoted around 70 US dollar per barrel.<br />

The historical oil price development is shown in Figure 2.2. Two prices are given:<br />

first, the price of a barrel in dollars of the day <strong>an</strong>d second, the price of a barrel in<br />

2005 US dollars to project the price development in nowadays scale. 5<br />

Figure 2.2: Crude Oil Historical Price Development<br />

After the first euphoria about oil’s usability at the end of the 19th century <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the establishment of refineries <strong>an</strong>d production infr<strong>as</strong>tructure, oil prices went into a<br />

long period of stability for around 100 years. The major oil reserves are located<br />

in the Middle E<strong>as</strong>t which account for around two thirds of world’s total reserves. 6<br />

5 See [BP Report 2006].<br />

6 See Table 2.1.<br />

8


2.1 The different Commodity Types<br />

Unfortunately, this region is characterized by political instability. The strong oil<br />

dependence of world’s industry <strong>an</strong>d its fear for supply interruptions causes oil prices<br />

to react heavily to queries in this countries. The first huge oil crises in 1973 w<strong>as</strong><br />

activated by the <strong>an</strong>nouncement of the Org<strong>an</strong>ization of the Petroleum Exporting<br />

Countries (OPEC) to stop oil exports to Western countries which supported Israel<br />

in the Yom-Kippur-War against Egypt. The second price surge w<strong>as</strong> caused by a<br />

revolution in the Ir<strong>an</strong> ending with a regime fall. With the new government ruled by<br />

Ayatollah Khomeini oil production w<strong>as</strong> noticeable decre<strong>as</strong>ed: In 1978 Ir<strong>an</strong> produced<br />

8.5% of world’s total production, in 1979 it w<strong>as</strong> only 5% of world’s total production<br />

<strong>an</strong>d in 1980 its output w<strong>as</strong> fallen to 2.4% of world’s total production. 7 The shocks<br />

during the l<strong>as</strong>t century generated a worldwide sensitivity to the dependence on oil<br />

resulting in different arr<strong>an</strong>gements to cut off this chain <strong>an</strong>d therefore, decre<strong>as</strong>ing dem<strong>an</strong>d<br />

followed by collapsing prices at the end of the century. The OPEC <strong>an</strong>d USA<br />

stabled prices with different engagements until 1990 <strong>as</strong> the first Golf War started.<br />

An interesting observation is that spot prices jumped up nearby 50% to over 35 US<br />

dollar per barrel but the market saw this incre<strong>as</strong>e <strong>as</strong> a short term movement: the<br />

twelve month later futures contract kept calm in price with 10 US dollar behind the<br />

first month contract. 8 Nowadays, this picture h<strong>as</strong> ch<strong>an</strong>ged. Since the 11th September<br />

of 2001 oil prices are rising <strong>an</strong>d it prices suspect that they will stay at a high<br />

level over a long period: the December 2012 futures contract is quoted only 10 US<br />

dollar behind the current spot price. This is indeed <strong>an</strong> indicator that we entered<br />

a long run high oil price period: The market is willing to pay over 65 US dollar<br />

per barrel crude oil that will be delivered in 6 years. Re<strong>as</strong>ons for this are m<strong>an</strong>ifold.<br />

Figure 2.3 presents the statistic about world’s oil reserves.<br />

Since the two major findings in 1986 9 <strong>an</strong>d worlds biggest finding in 1988 10 , no major<br />

oil field h<strong>as</strong> been discovered during the l<strong>as</strong>t 20 years.<br />

Analyzing the data of the [BP Report 2006] including all relev<strong>an</strong>t information regarding<br />

oil reserves, production <strong>an</strong>d consumption uncovers interesting insides: Middle<br />

E<strong>as</strong>t’s reserves remained nearly const<strong>an</strong>t <strong>an</strong>d the US reserves are decre<strong>as</strong>ing.<br />

Table 2.1 shows the distribution of the main oil sources of the world in percentage<br />

share of total world resources in 2005 r<strong>an</strong>ked by its size. All other countries have<br />

reserves below 3.5% of total world reserves in 2005.<br />

7 See [BP Report 2006].<br />

8 See Bloomberg, NYMEX crude oil futures contracts.<br />

9 over 40 billion barrels in Ir<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d over 60 billion barrels in the United Arab Emirates<br />

10 over 100 billion barrels in Saudi Arabia<br />

9


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

Figure 2.3: Crude Oil Reserves<br />

From this point of view someone c<strong>an</strong> underst<strong>an</strong>d Ir<strong>an</strong>’s <strong>an</strong>d Iraq’s import<strong>an</strong>ce for<br />

world oil markets <strong>an</strong>d the huge political efforts around these countries. Under the<br />

dictatorship of Saddam Hussein Iraq’s pumping output had reached scales equal to<br />

them of the United Arab Emirates. But since the war in 2003 it h<strong>as</strong> decre<strong>as</strong>ed around<br />

20%. Similarly, Ir<strong>an</strong> couldn’t catch up with former pumping quotes. This is pointed<br />

out in Table 2.1. It shows the production of the biggest resource owners worldwide:<br />

the ownership of oil does not go h<strong>an</strong>d in h<strong>an</strong>d with production. Although countries<br />

like the USA, Mexico, China, C<strong>an</strong>ada <strong>an</strong>d Norway have just a quarter of the reserves<br />

of Kuwait or the United Arab Emirates they support world’s economy more with<br />

higher production quotes <strong>as</strong> these countries do. However, the proved reserves still<br />

l<strong>as</strong>t for more th<strong>an</strong> 40 years but market particip<strong>an</strong>ts always gets nervous when things<br />

come to <strong>an</strong> end <strong>an</strong>d the ch<strong>an</strong>ge to substitutes is cost intensive.<br />

A contemporary issue is that the main part of the oil reserves are located in the<br />

political instable regions of the Middle E<strong>as</strong>t. Moreover, the USA <strong>as</strong> the world’s<br />

largest consumer by far had good relations to the Middle E<strong>as</strong>t <strong>an</strong>d became aware<br />

Country<br />

Reserves Production<br />

% of total r<strong>an</strong>k % of total r<strong>an</strong>k<br />

Saudi Arabia 22.0% 1 13.5% 1<br />

Ir<strong>an</strong> 11.5% 2 5.1% 4<br />

Iraq 9.6% 3 2.3% 3<br />

Kuwait 8.5% 4 3.3% 10<br />

United Arab Emirates 8.1% 5 3.3% 11<br />

Venezuela 6.6% 6 4.0% 7<br />

Russia 6.2% 7 12.1% 2<br />

Table 2.1: Oil Reserves <strong>an</strong>d Production<br />

10


2.1 The different Commodity Types<br />

after the 11th September of 2001 that huge problems bubble under the earth.<br />

The main problem of world’s dependence of the pumping quotes is the steady rising<br />

consumption. Figure 2.4 shows the daily net consumption (= production minus<br />

consumption) over the l<strong>as</strong>t centuries. 11<br />

Figure 2.4: Net Crude Oil Consumption<br />

Since 1981 consumption h<strong>as</strong> risen much f<strong>as</strong>ter th<strong>an</strong> production because of the production<br />

arr<strong>an</strong>gements between the USA <strong>an</strong>d the OPEC to stable prices during the<br />

1980th <strong>an</strong>d 1990th <strong>an</strong>d world’s growing industrialization, technological improvements<br />

<strong>an</strong>d electrification. Furthermore, the US output <strong>an</strong>d reserves have decre<strong>as</strong>ed<br />

since 2000 <strong>an</strong>d so did Norway’s. Indonesia reached the break even point l<strong>as</strong>t year<br />

where production <strong>an</strong>d consumption netted off each other <strong>an</strong>d the country is expected<br />

to ch<strong>an</strong>ge from a net exporter to a net importer.<br />

Although the OPEC<br />

h<strong>as</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>ed pumping quotes, re<strong>as</strong>ons mentioned above let to huge negative bars<br />

since 1997 representing the under production <strong>an</strong>d over consumption. Consequently<br />

world’s inventories are low today. Especially the Asia Pacific region h<strong>as</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>ed<br />

its oil consumption extraordinary. China h<strong>as</strong> on average heightened its consumption<br />

around 8.5% p.a. over the l<strong>as</strong>t 10 years. It h<strong>as</strong> grown to the second largest consumer<br />

of crude oil with a yearly share of total world consumption of 8.5%, topped by the<br />

USA with a yearly share of 25% <strong>an</strong>d followed by Jap<strong>an</strong> with a share of 6.5% in<br />

2005. 12 But still, China’s barrel per capita usage of oil is very low: it uses 0.005<br />

barrel per day per capita. In comparison, the USA uses 0.07 barrel per day per<br />

capita <strong>an</strong>d Jap<strong>an</strong> uses 0.04 barrel per day per capita. 13<br />

11 See [BP Report 2006].<br />

12 See [BP Report 2006].<br />

13 Population data source : Census Bureau of the U.S. Department of Commerce (www.census.gov).<br />

11


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

The major problem for the future will be that China is a gi<strong>an</strong>t emerging market<br />

<strong>an</strong>d emerging markets have according to experience a higher dem<strong>an</strong>d el<strong>as</strong>ticity th<strong>an</strong><br />

industrial countries. While industrial growth in Western countries is followed by <strong>an</strong><br />

oil dem<strong>an</strong>d growth of one third, industrial growth in emerging countries is followed<br />

by <strong>an</strong> oil dem<strong>an</strong>d growth of two thirds. 14 For inst<strong>an</strong>ce, if the USA industry grows<br />

around 3% per <strong>an</strong>num this is followed by <strong>an</strong> oil dem<strong>an</strong>d incre<strong>as</strong>e of 1%. If the<br />

Chinese industry growths around 3% per <strong>an</strong>num this comes in line with <strong>an</strong> oil<br />

dem<strong>an</strong>d incre<strong>as</strong>e with 2%. During the l<strong>as</strong>t 5 years the Chinese economy grew around<br />

9.5% per <strong>an</strong>num while the USA economy grew around 6% per <strong>an</strong>num. This data<br />

forec<strong>as</strong>t a further dem<strong>an</strong>d incre<strong>as</strong>e over the next years.<br />

Nevertheless, there are movements to switch to alternative energy sources but substituting<br />

long term grown established structures will take a while but will move on<br />

in a high oil price environment. Because crude oil is the input factor for m<strong>an</strong>y retail<br />

products like heating oil or g<strong>as</strong>oline, comp<strong>an</strong>ies p<strong>as</strong>s through high crude oil prices<br />

to consumers. High costs for heating <strong>an</strong>d tr<strong>an</strong>sport cut off net salaries like higher<br />

taxes. If no ch<strong>an</strong>ge is expected over a longer period, people are likely to switch<br />

to alternative energy sources although the ch<strong>an</strong>ge is connected to <strong>an</strong> one time investment.<br />

This movement c<strong>an</strong> already be discovered in Europe <strong>an</strong>d the USA where<br />

biofuels, solar cells or natural g<strong>as</strong> are getting more popular.<br />

2.1.1.2 Natural G<strong>as</strong><br />

Natural G<strong>as</strong> is a fossil fuel that is colorless, shapeless, <strong>an</strong>d odorless in its pure form.<br />

It is combusting, cle<strong>an</strong> burning, <strong>an</strong>d gives off a great deal of energy. Around 500 BC,<br />

Chinese were the first who discovered that the energy in natural g<strong>as</strong> c<strong>an</strong> be used.<br />

They p<strong>as</strong>sed it through bamboo-shoot pipes <strong>an</strong>d then burned it to boil sea water to<br />

get potable fresh water. In the 18th <strong>an</strong>d 19th century natural g<strong>as</strong> w<strong>as</strong> introduced to<br />

Europe <strong>an</strong>d the USA. There is a v<strong>as</strong>t amount of natural g<strong>as</strong> estimated still to be in<br />

the ground. Today, the Russi<strong>an</strong> Federation is the major producer worldwide with<br />

a share of total world production of around 22%, followed by the USA with a share<br />

of total world production of around 19% <strong>an</strong>d by far third C<strong>an</strong>ada with a share of<br />

total world production of around 7%.<br />

Natural g<strong>as</strong> is getting more popular <strong>an</strong>d h<strong>as</strong> the potential to grow to a real alternative<br />

to crude oil. First, only 40% of its reserves are located in the political instable<br />

Middle E<strong>as</strong>t <strong>an</strong>d second, natural g<strong>as</strong> burns cle<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d with little air pollution implicating<br />

<strong>an</strong> environmental adv<strong>an</strong>tage to crude oil <strong>an</strong>d coal. Natural g<strong>as</strong> w<strong>as</strong> formed<br />

14 See[UBS research 2005].<br />

12


2.1 The different Commodity Types<br />

in the same way like petroleum <strong>an</strong>d occurs to 30% in combination with its liquid<br />

brother <strong>an</strong>d to 70% in independent fields. Figure 2.5 shows its price <strong>an</strong>d net consumption<br />

development over the l<strong>as</strong>t 35 years in the scale of oil equivalent for better<br />

comparison.<br />

Figure 2.5: Natural G<strong>as</strong> Price <strong>an</strong>d Net Consumption<br />

Natural g<strong>as</strong> prices are by far not that volatile <strong>as</strong> crude oil prices are <strong>an</strong>d are by<br />

far not that reactive to political queries because it does not have the import<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

in world’s industry, yet. It c<strong>an</strong> be seen <strong>as</strong> a substitute to crude oil what is getting<br />

specially in <strong>an</strong> high oil cost environment more popular. Its major drawback to<br />

petroleum is that is comes <strong>as</strong> a g<strong>as</strong>. Therefore, its volume is thous<strong>an</strong>d times that of<br />

its liquet brother. Since the 1960s there exist procedures which cool down natural<br />

g<strong>as</strong> until it goes over into the liquid state of aggregation. In this form it c<strong>an</strong> be<br />

stored <strong>an</strong>d shipped or driven to its place of destination. This procedure is more<br />

complicated <strong>an</strong>d cost intensive <strong>as</strong> the storage <strong>an</strong>d tr<strong>an</strong>sportation of oil. Therefore,<br />

the industrial use of natural g<strong>as</strong> becomes economically justifiable only in a high oil<br />

cost environment.<br />

As we’ve already mentioned, there are different movements to switch from oil b<strong>as</strong>ed<br />

products to alternative energy sources what explains the higher consumption growth<br />

rates of 2.5% on average over the l<strong>as</strong>t 10 years in comparison to crude oil which usage<br />

h<strong>as</strong> been grown on average 1.7% over the l<strong>as</strong>t 10 years. 15 Natural g<strong>as</strong> c<strong>an</strong> be used<br />

to substitute traditional heating <strong>an</strong>d electricity sources. M<strong>an</strong>y households already<br />

started to switch their heating fuel from oil to g<strong>as</strong> what incre<strong>as</strong>ed its dem<strong>an</strong>d. Over<br />

this, car m<strong>an</strong>ufacturers are working to get fuel cell b<strong>as</strong>ed motors ready for commercial<br />

use. First test series have been successfully but bulk production stills needs<br />

15 See [BP Report 2006].<br />

13


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

some time because the technology is not stable yet, especially in cold temperature<br />

regions. Furthermore, a g<strong>as</strong> station infr<strong>as</strong>tructure is not established, yet.<br />

Summing up, natural g<strong>as</strong> h<strong>as</strong> the potential to become one of the leading energy<br />

sources during the next years. Especially China will be a major consumer. Growing<br />

concerns about pollution from coal burning, China’s major energy source at the<br />

moment, have forced the government to turn to cle<strong>an</strong>er burning fuels. Especially in<br />

parts where access to coal resources is limited, a number of reg<strong>as</strong>ification pl<strong>an</strong>ts are<br />

currently under construction or pl<strong>an</strong>ned. 16<br />

Closing this section, we will show the structural ch<strong>an</strong>ge in market dependencies<br />

when one product is used <strong>as</strong> substitute for <strong>an</strong>other. Therefore, Figure 2.6 shows the<br />

historical price movements of natural g<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong>d crude oil.<br />

Figure 2.6: Natural G<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong>d Crude Oil Prices<br />

Taking a closer look we realize that the price movements became more similar over<br />

the years. Indeed, the correlation between the two energy products incre<strong>as</strong>ed over<br />

time. While there does not exist a statistically signific<strong>an</strong>t correlation between relative<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the price series during the periods 1980-1989 <strong>an</strong>d 1990-1999 a<br />

correlation of 0.23 is signific<strong>an</strong>t at the 5% alpha level during the period 2000-2006. 17<br />

The incre<strong>as</strong>ing dependence between the two commodities reflects the substitution<br />

of crude oil with natural g<strong>as</strong>: when crude oil prices rise market particip<strong>an</strong>ts switch<br />

to natural g<strong>as</strong>.<br />

This movement incre<strong>as</strong>es the dem<strong>an</strong>d for natural g<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong>d prices<br />

are rising. Moreover, this movement incre<strong>as</strong>es the dependence on steady supply of<br />

16 See [EIA Outlook 2006].<br />

17 For this <strong>an</strong>alysis we took monthly c<strong>as</strong>h data of the [The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005]<br />

completed with Bloomberg data for 2005 <strong>an</strong>d 2006. We used monthly log returns <strong>as</strong> of<br />

Definition C.2. For the mathematical definition of Pearson correlation <strong>an</strong>d the related statistical<br />

test see Section 5.1.2.<br />

14


2.1 The different Commodity Types<br />

natural g<strong>as</strong>. Therefore, nervous market reactions to possible supply interruptions<br />

c<strong>an</strong> occur. Hurric<strong>an</strong>e Katrina destroyed major pipelines in Oklahoma. The reaction<br />

of the market c<strong>an</strong> clearly be seen in the huge amplitude of natural g<strong>as</strong> prices in<br />

August 2005.<br />

2.1.2 Metals<br />

Figure 2.1 showed that metals are divided into two big groups: the precious <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

industrial metals which will be introduced in this section.<br />

Precious metals have attracted people with living memory. In former times mainly<br />

used in jewelery, they moved into industrial usage, today. Their representatives<br />

include gold, platinum, palladium <strong>an</strong>d silver. They are mainly used in electric <strong>an</strong>d<br />

computer circuit. The strong market exp<strong>an</strong>sion in this area resulted in a high dem<strong>an</strong>d<br />

for this metals. But for investors gold is still the most attractive representative<br />

of this group. The re<strong>as</strong>on for this c<strong>an</strong> be found in golds role <strong>as</strong> international currency<br />

<strong>an</strong>d with it <strong>as</strong> store of value. Therefore, its characteristics <strong>an</strong>d price influencing factors<br />

are presented in Section 2.1.2.1 <strong>an</strong>d shall exemplify <strong>an</strong> investment in precious<br />

metals. The history of gold is affected by times of the so-called gold st<strong>an</strong>dard <strong>as</strong><br />

different world currencies were backed up by gold’s value. The l<strong>as</strong>t period ended in<br />

1971 <strong>as</strong> world’s leading currency, the US dollar, w<strong>as</strong> disconnected from gold’s value.<br />

The purpose of the <strong>an</strong>alysis is to find out whether the gold price movements of l<strong>as</strong>t<br />

years are still connected to world currencies or not.<br />

Industrial metals are mainly used in construction <strong>an</strong>d building of infr<strong>as</strong>tructure,<br />

tr<strong>an</strong>sportation <strong>an</strong>d housing. During the 1980s metals industry went through a regression.<br />

Technological improvements enabled savings in materials, e.g. cars became<br />

lighter or aluminium <strong>an</strong>d steel were substituted by strong but lighter carbon compounds.<br />

Falling prices made the industry line unattractive. Production w<strong>as</strong> driven<br />

down <strong>an</strong>d investments in new production are<strong>as</strong> disappeared. With the boom of<br />

emerging country’s economies, the dem<strong>an</strong>d for industrial metals incre<strong>as</strong>ed sharply<br />

because new production pl<strong>an</strong>ts <strong>an</strong>d infr<strong>as</strong>tructure were needed <strong>an</strong>d followed by a<br />

housing boom <strong>as</strong> st<strong>an</strong>dards of living incre<strong>as</strong>ed. Everybody knows the headlines<br />

about ”China - works ahead!”. The activities pulled of huge amounts of the metals<br />

for what the industry w<strong>as</strong> not prepared. The <strong>an</strong>alysis’ of Appendix B.4 to B.8 show<br />

the inventory destroying effects of these movements followed by rising prices. The<br />

main problem in metals production is the tediousness of the industrial development<br />

of new mines <strong>an</strong>d refineries. In general, m<strong>an</strong>y years p<strong>as</strong>s by from the exploration of<br />

a new ore deposit until the first hammer blow. Apply for <strong>an</strong> official digging approval<br />

15


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

is time consuming, investors need to be found <strong>an</strong>d equipment <strong>an</strong>d machinery need<br />

to be delivered. Moreover, production costs incre<strong>as</strong>ed sharply: the cost for <strong>an</strong> open<br />

pit quintupled over the l<strong>as</strong>t ten years <strong>an</strong>d reached 500 million US dollar in 2006. All<br />

these factors resulted into a fundamental ch<strong>an</strong>ge of the industry explained in the<br />

Section 2.1.2.2.<br />

2.1.2.1 Precious Metals exemplified by Gold<br />

The dense, bright yellow metallic element called gold put a spell on people since its<br />

first discovery. Egypti<strong>an</strong>s mined gold since 2,000 BC <strong>an</strong>d worked it up to jewelery<br />

for beauty <strong>an</strong>d religious purposes. Over this, gold is the oldest international currency<br />

<strong>an</strong>d h<strong>as</strong> played a role in most countries’ currency systems for well over 2,000<br />

years. Gold’s scarcity, the fact that it does not corrode or tarnish, coupled with its<br />

malleability so that coins c<strong>an</strong> e<strong>as</strong>ily be shaped <strong>an</strong>d the way in which it h<strong>as</strong> been<br />

prized in all civilizations, have made it eminently suitable <strong>as</strong> a form of money. The<br />

first pure gold coin appeared on the orders of King Croesus of Lydia around 550 BC.<br />

During the Middle Ages in Europe, gold <strong>an</strong>d silver formed the b<strong>as</strong>is of the currency<br />

systems. Although, gold w<strong>as</strong> too valuable for most day-to-day tr<strong>an</strong>sactions, it w<strong>as</strong><br />

used <strong>as</strong> backup system. The so-called gold st<strong>an</strong>dard defines a monetary system that<br />

h<strong>as</strong> linked its currency’s value to gold prices at a fixed rate. The only st<strong>an</strong>dardized<br />

international gold st<strong>an</strong>dard existed for a comprehensive short period from the<br />

1870th until the outbreak of the First World War in 1914. A crucial adv<strong>an</strong>tage<br />

of the gold st<strong>an</strong>dard w<strong>as</strong> the certainty of foreign investors, that the value of their<br />

investment w<strong>as</strong> unlikely to be hurt by the depreciation of the recipient country’s<br />

currency relative to their own. This facilitated large flows of international direct investments.<br />

The capital enabled the f<strong>as</strong>t development of the United States, C<strong>an</strong>ada,<br />

Australia <strong>an</strong>d other emerging markets of that days. Relative to the size of world’s<br />

economy, these flows were <strong>as</strong> large or even larger th<strong>an</strong> today’s <strong>an</strong>d they were far less<br />

volatile. 18<br />

During the worldwide queries of the period between the two world wars it w<strong>as</strong> not<br />

possible to establish a new gold st<strong>an</strong>dard. First in 1944 a new gold st<strong>an</strong>dard w<strong>as</strong><br />

introduced by p<strong>as</strong>sing the Bretton Woods Convention. It fixed the US dollar to 35<br />

US dollar per ounce while other currencies were defined in terms of the dollar with<br />

fixed but with authorization of the International Monetary Funds adjustable rates.<br />

The US dollar w<strong>as</strong> chosen because the USA were the one country worldwide what<br />

18 See World Gold Council.<br />

16


2.1 The different Commodity Types<br />

hold credible gold reserves to back their currency. 19 The system finally failed caused<br />

by two major drawbacks:<br />

1. The dollar w<strong>as</strong> on the one h<strong>an</strong>d the international reference currency but on the<br />

other h<strong>an</strong>d the currency of the USA. It therefore could ch<strong>an</strong>ge its monetary<br />

policy without bearing <strong>an</strong>y consequences. Indeed all countries involved in the<br />

Bretton Woods Convention fin<strong>an</strong>ced a part of the huge budged deficit the USA<br />

had cumulated during the Vietnam War what w<strong>as</strong> payed with printing new<br />

money.<br />

2. The creditability of the USA decre<strong>as</strong>ed dr<strong>as</strong>tic because Germ<strong>an</strong>y <strong>an</strong>d Fr<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ged their dollars into gold. At the end of the 1960th the gold reserves of<br />

the USA had fallen around one third. 20<br />

Finally US-President Richard Nixon ab<strong>an</strong>doned the system in 1971. The l<strong>as</strong>t fixing<br />

price before the ”gold window” w<strong>as</strong> closed w<strong>as</strong> 42.22 US dollar per troy ounce, <strong>an</strong>d<br />

to this price the United States officially valued its gold holdings. Figure 2.7 shows<br />

the long term movements of the gold price <strong>an</strong>d its free flow since 1971.<br />

Figure 2.7: Gold Price Movements between 1960-2006<br />

The newest study about the behavior of gold prices in <strong>an</strong> international environment<br />

by [Levin Wright 2006] h<strong>as</strong> pointed out the major drivers of gold prices in the<br />

short <strong>an</strong>d long run. For the first c<strong>as</strong>e, the authors named ch<strong>an</strong>ges of the following<br />

economic indicators to be statistically positively correlated with ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the<br />

gold price: US inflation, US inflation volatility <strong>an</strong>d credit risk. On the other h<strong>an</strong>d,<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the US dollar trade-weighted exch<strong>an</strong>ge rate, what reflects the value of<br />

19 At this point in history the USA hold 70% of worldwide gold reserves. See [UBS research 2005].<br />

20 See [UBS research 2005].<br />

17


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

the US dollar in terms of a b<strong>as</strong>ket of the major world currencies, is statistically<br />

signific<strong>an</strong>t negatively correlated to ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the gold price. The second finding<br />

is mentioned in [UBS research 2005] <strong>as</strong> well <strong>an</strong>d c<strong>an</strong> be seen in Figure 2.8. 21 The<br />

correlation between ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the gold price <strong>an</strong>d ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the US dollar tradeweighted<br />

index is signific<strong>an</strong>t with -0.44. Although, the gold st<strong>an</strong>dard h<strong>as</strong> dropped<br />

m<strong>an</strong>y years ago, ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the value of the US dollar <strong>an</strong>d gold exhibit still a strong<br />

dependence structure. Moreover, the high negative correlation suspects, that investors<br />

view gold <strong>as</strong> a storage of wealth.<br />

Figure 2.8: Today’s Gold Price Dependence of the US dollar<br />

In the long run [Levin Wright 2006] could proof the statistical signific<strong>an</strong>ce of a positive<br />

dependence between the gold price <strong>an</strong>d the US price level.<br />

Summing up, the research indeed showed that the connection between the gold price<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the US dollar never disengaged because m<strong>an</strong>y investors still trust gold to be<br />

a wealth carrier <strong>an</strong>d <strong>as</strong> a currency hedge. In the period between 1996 <strong>an</strong>d 2000<br />

gold lost more th<strong>an</strong> one quarter of its value. This w<strong>as</strong> caused by a strong Americ<strong>an</strong><br />

stock market attracting huge amounts of capital <strong>an</strong>d a sold out of gold reserves by<br />

Europe<strong>an</strong> Central B<strong>an</strong>ks to st<strong>an</strong>dardize their gold reserves to prepare themselves for<br />

the introduction of the Euro. Nowadays, the gold price incre<strong>as</strong>ed strongly caused<br />

by the problems of the USA resulting in a dollar watering place <strong>an</strong>d a run out of<br />

dollar investments. Specially countries out of the Middle <strong>an</strong>d Far E<strong>as</strong>t are backing<br />

up their wealth with gold.<br />

The historical relev<strong>an</strong>ce of gold <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> international currency provides this commodity<br />

with special features. A simple <strong>an</strong>alysis of supply <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d is not enough to<br />

21 Data source: Bloomberg. We used monthly log returns <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.2. For the mathematical<br />

definition of Pearson correlation <strong>an</strong>d the related statistical test see Section 5.1.2.<br />

18


2.1 The different Commodity Types<br />

show its value. In fact, geopolitical circumst<strong>an</strong>ces outweigh fundamental commodity<br />

market <strong>an</strong>alysis. Nevertheless, this part of the valuation of gold should not be<br />

forgotten <strong>an</strong>d is done in Appendix B.3. Because gold still is a commodity, supply<br />

interruptions or surpluses <strong>an</strong>d abrupt surges or collapses in dem<strong>an</strong>d c<strong>an</strong> cause prices<br />

to rise or to fall.<br />

2.1.2.2 Industrial Metals<br />

Metals became one of the most subst<strong>an</strong>tial elements in our daily life. But who thinks<br />

about that our mobile phones, ballpoint pens <strong>an</strong>d the aluminium foil in the kitchen<br />

are made of stone?<br />

Mining h<strong>as</strong> been performed since prehistoric times. The people of the Stone Age<br />

used different kinds of mineral quartz for weapons <strong>an</strong>d tools. The first metal that<br />

hum<strong>an</strong>s learned to mine <strong>an</strong>d shape w<strong>as</strong> copper. This w<strong>as</strong> the beginning of the<br />

period historically called the age of metal. The oldest known metal mines are the<br />

copper mines at Sinai dating back to 5,000 BC. The oldest known war aiming up<br />

to conquer natural resources w<strong>as</strong> around 2,600 BC under the Egypti<strong>an</strong> pharaoh<br />

Sechemchet who <strong>an</strong>nexed Sinai with the only purpose to <strong>an</strong>nex its copper mines.<br />

When people discovered that alloying copper <strong>an</strong>d tin produced a stronger <strong>an</strong>d more<br />

durable metal, the so-called Bronze Age started in the Cauc<strong>as</strong>us around 4,000 BC.<br />

From there, the technology spread rapidly all over the Near E<strong>as</strong>t. Iron beg<strong>an</strong> to be<br />

worked already in Late Bronze Age but w<strong>as</strong> hardly m<strong>an</strong>ageable. Traditions tell that<br />

mystery maritime people brought war <strong>an</strong>d destruction <strong>an</strong>d the fluctuating trade of<br />

this times broke down. While people run out of copper, iron ores could be found<br />

<strong>an</strong>d extracted nearly everywhere. As people finally were able to h<strong>an</strong>dle iron, the<br />

tr<strong>an</strong>sition into the Iron Age around 1,200 BC w<strong>as</strong> more of a political ch<strong>an</strong>ge rather<br />

th<strong>an</strong> of new developments in metalworking. The adv<strong>an</strong>tages of iron in comparison<br />

to bronze were hardness, durability <strong>an</strong>d cheapness.<br />

As civilization developed, the need <strong>an</strong>d the search for minerals accelerated <strong>an</strong>d with<br />

this the trade of metals. The Phoenici<strong>an</strong>s crossed the Mediterr<strong>an</strong>e<strong>an</strong> Sea to work the<br />

copper mines of southern Spain, <strong>an</strong>d their ships sailed to the British Isles to trade<br />

for tin. The Rom<strong>an</strong>s improved the mining practices in the l<strong>an</strong>ds <strong>an</strong>d first mined<br />

on a large scale, including amongst others the copper <strong>an</strong>d tin ores in Cornwall <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Wales. In 1571, the first place w<strong>as</strong> founded in London where traders of metal <strong>an</strong>d a<br />

r<strong>an</strong>ge of other commodities beg<strong>an</strong> to meet on a regular b<strong>as</strong>is. Because Britain soon<br />

became a major exporter of metals, Europe<strong>an</strong> merch<strong>an</strong>ts arrived to join in these<br />

activities. Later, the coal mines <strong>an</strong>d nation’s production of iron <strong>an</strong>d steel provided<br />

19


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

the b<strong>as</strong>is for the Industrial Revolution <strong>an</strong>d almost overnight, Great Britain became<br />

the most technologically adv<strong>an</strong>ced country in the world, importing large tonnage’s<br />

from all over the world. The major problem w<strong>as</strong> the price uncertainty. Metal traders<br />

having bought ores from <strong>as</strong> far <strong>as</strong> Chile <strong>an</strong>d Malaya had no way of knowing what<br />

price would predominate at the time of the ships arrival some month later. Merch<strong>an</strong>ts<br />

<strong>an</strong>d consumers had to face serious price risks. Technology came to their aid<br />

with the invention of the telegraph. Inter continental lines of communication were<br />

established between the countries of the world <strong>an</strong>d the ch<strong>an</strong>ge from sail to steam<br />

ships made arrival dates more predictable. In 1869 the Suez C<strong>an</strong>al w<strong>as</strong> opened <strong>an</strong>d<br />

therewith delivery times reduced to three month. The unique three month forward<br />

contract w<strong>as</strong> established <strong>an</strong>d is still alive at the London Metals Exch<strong>an</strong>ge (LME)<br />

what w<strong>as</strong> founded in 1877. 22 Copper <strong>an</strong>d tin were the first metals that were traded.<br />

In 1920, lead <strong>an</strong>d tin joint <strong>an</strong>d at the end of the 1970th aluminium <strong>an</strong>d nickel were<br />

introduced <strong>as</strong> well. Finally, in 1999 a silver contract w<strong>as</strong> launched. All contracts<br />

are still traded open outcry circling in a five minute period known <strong>as</strong> the ”ring”.<br />

The London Metals Exch<strong>an</strong>ge Index (LMEX) reflecting the price movements of all<br />

six metals gives market particip<strong>an</strong>ts since its inception in 2000 <strong>an</strong> overview of the<br />

industrial metals market development. Figure 2.9 plots the index value evolvement<br />

since its inception. 23<br />

Figure 2.9: The London Metals Exch<strong>an</strong>ge Index<br />

We clearly observe a strong upward trend during the l<strong>as</strong>t years. The major re<strong>as</strong>on<br />

for this is a strong dem<strong>an</strong>d from China <strong>an</strong>d India since 2002. Over 20% of copper,<br />

aluminium <strong>an</strong>d zinc world production <strong>an</strong>d nearby every second cargo of iron ore<br />

22 For further details see [LME 2006].<br />

23 Data source: Bloomberg.<br />

20


2.1 The different Commodity Types<br />

went to China in 2005. 24 Rising prices are highly correlated with a falling stock of<br />

inventory. Pushing production in metals markets is neither e<strong>as</strong>y nor quick. New<br />

mines have to be cultivated <strong>an</strong>d infr<strong>as</strong>tructure in processing <strong>an</strong>d tr<strong>an</strong>sportation<br />

h<strong>as</strong> to be built. This is mostly combined with environmental s<strong>an</strong>ctions which to<br />

get c<strong>an</strong> l<strong>as</strong>t for years, especially in industrial countries. Because of the low margins<br />

during the 1980th <strong>an</strong>d 1990th the industry didn’t invest yielding into capacity bottle<br />

necks at the beginning of the 21rst century followed by the biggest price surge in<br />

metals markets ever. Industry’s huge gains of the l<strong>as</strong>t five years were invested in <strong>an</strong><br />

acquisition relay, so that today only a couple of mining gi<strong>an</strong>ts, including Rio Tinto,<br />

BHP Billiton <strong>an</strong>d Anglo Americ<strong>an</strong>, rule the market. No other industry went through<br />

such a fundamental structural ch<strong>an</strong>ge. Buying other comp<strong>an</strong>ies me<strong>an</strong>s buying their<br />

mines <strong>an</strong>d knowing what you get for your money. Self exploration projects are by far<br />

more risky. But now where only the big survivors are left <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d still exceeds<br />

production, the industry need to go down the traditional road: Rio Tinto will invest<br />

three billion US dollar in both years 2006 <strong>an</strong>d 2007. BHB Billion will invest 12<br />

billion in the exploration of new mines. But this c<strong>an</strong> l<strong>as</strong>t until five to ten years <strong>an</strong>d<br />

even more caused by the re<strong>as</strong>ons mentioned introductory to this section. 25<br />

Moreover, the industry faces further problems with machinery <strong>an</strong>d educated staff.<br />

While m<strong>an</strong>y geologists needed to drive taxi during the 1990th they account to the<br />

most questioned employees, today. The waiting times of Caterpillar, Komatsu <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Liebherr for the gi<strong>an</strong>t trucks, costing around three million US dollar <strong>an</strong>d needed to<br />

tr<strong>an</strong>sport the raw ores in the mining sites, are around 18 month <strong>an</strong>d were supplied<br />

partly without wheels because its producers Michelin <strong>an</strong>d Bridgestone are still afraid<br />

to extend their production.<br />

Although, there is no end in sight in metals reserves because not all mines are<br />

explored yet, putting all these factors together the agers for a long period of high<br />

metal prices is given. Appendix B.4 to B.8 will further give a small inside into the<br />

production <strong>an</strong>d consumption structure of some selected metals including aluminium,<br />

copper, lead, nickel <strong>an</strong>d zinc.<br />

2.1.3 Agricultures<br />

The agricultural market is the most heterogenous market of the three main commodity<br />

groups. Figure 2.1 introduced its three sub groups: softs, grains <strong>an</strong>d livestock.<br />

While energy <strong>an</strong>d metals already went through a huge price surge, agricultures, with<br />

24 See [<strong>Commodities</strong> 2006].<br />

25 See [<strong>Commodities</strong> 2006].<br />

21


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

the exception of sugar, are lacking behind.<br />

The softs group includes cocoa, coffee <strong>an</strong>d sugar. It is internally the most heterogenous<br />

group of the agricultures because it constituencies are no substitutes or<br />

competitors among each other <strong>an</strong>d are no input or output factors for each other.<br />

They only have two things in common: First, they are agricultural products <strong>an</strong>d<br />

therewith, their prices are highly dependent to weather conditions <strong>an</strong>d field pests.<br />

Second, they are used to produce luxury products like c<strong>an</strong>dies <strong>an</strong>d p<strong>as</strong>tries. Therefore,<br />

their scale of usage depends on the st<strong>an</strong>dard of living in a country. Cocoa will<br />

be discussed in Section 2.1.3.1 <strong>an</strong>d shall serve us <strong>as</strong> the representative of the softs<br />

group. As a tropical pl<strong>an</strong>t it’s mainly grown in Africa. Overproduction pitched the<br />

industry into a regression at the end of the l<strong>as</strong>t century. But political queries yielded<br />

to production interruptions <strong>an</strong>d prices became stable over the l<strong>as</strong>t years. Coffee will<br />

be discussed in Appendix B.10. It is interesting to know that its world consumption<br />

h<strong>as</strong> grown 10% with the introduction of starbucks. 26 When we look around seeing<br />

new coffee shops from different comp<strong>an</strong>ies, including starbucks, coffee be<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d s<strong>an</strong><br />

fr<strong>an</strong>cisco coffee comp<strong>an</strong>y, mushrooming everywhere, price potential c<strong>an</strong> be <strong>as</strong>sumed.<br />

During the l<strong>as</strong>t two years sugar went through a renaiss<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>as</strong> described detailed in<br />

Appendix B.9. Traditionally, only used to produce c<strong>an</strong>dy <strong>an</strong>d p<strong>as</strong>tries, it became<br />

on vogue for eth<strong>an</strong>ol production. Eth<strong>an</strong>ol is used <strong>as</strong> intermixture to g<strong>as</strong>oline <strong>as</strong><br />

alternative fuel. Br<strong>as</strong>ilia is the heaviest user worldwide <strong>an</strong>d the sudden dem<strong>an</strong>d<br />

pushed sugar prices through the roof. This is one of the best examples how high<br />

energy prices <strong>an</strong>d the search for alternatives to oil <strong>an</strong>d oil products beam on other<br />

markets.<br />

The group of grains is one of the biggest commodity groups including corn, different<br />

kinds of wheat, barley, soybe<strong>an</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d rice. Actually soybe<strong>an</strong>s are a member of the<br />

oilseed family but they are generally mentioned under this commodity group for<br />

convenience. Grains are used <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong>imal feed or hum<strong>an</strong> food. As <strong>an</strong> agriculture<br />

their prices are weather dependent <strong>as</strong> all agricultural prices are. When it comes to<br />

agricultural investment corn, wheat <strong>an</strong>d soybe<strong>an</strong>s are the most traded constituencies.<br />

Because corn <strong>an</strong>d wheat are substitutes to each other we will just introduce corn<br />

to get <strong>an</strong> idea of the market in Section 2.1.3.2. Historically, corn is mostly used<br />

<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong>imal feed but with the search for new alternative bio fuels it found a new<br />

application. The same happened to soybe<strong>an</strong>s. The soybe<strong>an</strong> complex including<br />

soybe<strong>an</strong>s, soybe<strong>an</strong> meal <strong>an</strong>d soybe<strong>an</strong> oil <strong>an</strong>d its market characteristics are described<br />

in Appendix B.11. Traditionally, soybe<strong>an</strong>s were just used for <strong>an</strong>imal <strong>an</strong>d hum<strong>an</strong><br />

food but this ch<strong>an</strong>ged in a high energy price environment.<br />

26 See [Rogers 2005].<br />

22


2.1 The different Commodity Types<br />

Closing this section in 2.1.3.3, we will introduce live <strong>an</strong>d feeder cattle <strong>as</strong> the major<br />

exch<strong>an</strong>ge traded representatives of livestock, the l<strong>as</strong>t big sub group of the agricultural<br />

commodities. We will see that the major influencing factors of a potential<br />

investment in this commodity group are price stability in grains markets <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>imal<br />

epidemics. First, livestock prices are influenced by their production costs including<br />

costs for corn, wheat <strong>an</strong>d soybe<strong>an</strong>s. Therefore, this group of agricultural commodities<br />

is indirectly driven by weather conditions having direct impact on the input<br />

product feed. Second, the major direct risk factor in livestock markets are epidemics<br />

that require to destroy huge herd amounts. Nevertheless, trading le<strong>an</strong> hogs<br />

is getting more popular <strong>as</strong> well <strong>an</strong>d new products enable investors to ”feed” hogs<br />

”on paper”. This is described in Appendix B.12.<br />

2.1.3.1 Softs exemplified by Cocoa<br />

500 years ago, Sp<strong>an</strong>ish discoverer found a pl<strong>an</strong>t in South America <strong>an</strong>d called it<br />

cocoa ”the food of the gods”. Today, it remains a valued commodity used to produce<br />

chocolate <strong>an</strong>d cocoa powder for direct sale or bakery articles <strong>an</strong>d cocoa butter mainly<br />

used for bakery articles, soap <strong>an</strong>d cosmetics. The scope of application is not driven<br />

by possible sudden dem<strong>an</strong>d shocks. The sensitive factor is production that might<br />

be interrupted by bad weather conditions. Figure 2.10 shows the historical cocoa<br />

price development since 1960.<br />

Figure 2.10: Cocoa Be<strong>an</strong> Price<br />

The huge price incre<strong>as</strong>e in the 1970s w<strong>as</strong> caused by the US hyper inflation inducing<br />

a general commodity price incre<strong>as</strong>e. In 2006, cocoa costs on average 71 cents per<br />

pound that is around 5 cents above its average price since 1960 of 65 cents. Two<br />

thirds of world production comes from Africa whereby Cote d’Ivories with 39% of<br />

23


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

world supply in 2005 is with far dist<strong>an</strong>ce to Gh<strong>an</strong>a with 18% of world supply in 2005<br />

the biggest producer. Europe is with 43% of world consumption the biggest user.<br />

Amazing, that the small Netherl<strong>an</strong>ds with its 16 million people spent 14% of world<br />

consumption followed by the USA with its 300 million people <strong>an</strong>d 13% of world<br />

consumption. Figure 2.11 gives <strong>an</strong> overview of world consumption <strong>an</strong>d production<br />

in comparison to price movements. 27<br />

Figure 2.11: Cocoa Be<strong>an</strong> Price <strong>an</strong>d Net Consumption Ch<strong>an</strong>ge<br />

The dark bar series shows the cumulated net consumption starting in 1995, i.e.<br />

<strong>as</strong>suming that production <strong>an</strong>d consumption started in 1995 the series shows the<br />

development of inventories over the l<strong>as</strong>t 10 years. The light bar series shows the<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ge in yearly net consumption, i.e. the bar is positive when there w<strong>as</strong> more<br />

production th<strong>an</strong> consumption in the year <strong>an</strong>d vise versa. The or<strong>an</strong>ge line shows<br />

the realized average price per year <strong>an</strong>d indicates consequently the market reaction<br />

to inventory levels. In 1999, there w<strong>as</strong> a huge over bid caused by <strong>an</strong> extraordinary<br />

harvest in Africa. Inventories incre<strong>as</strong>ed heavily what caused prices to fall. Cocoa<br />

prices dropped to their 25 year low with 40 cents per pound. The reaction w<strong>as</strong><br />

that Brazil <strong>an</strong>d Malaysia noticeable reduced their production <strong>an</strong>d ch<strong>an</strong>ged to other<br />

crops. Over the l<strong>as</strong>t year production <strong>an</strong>d consumption nearby netted off what w<strong>as</strong><br />

caused by a strong dem<strong>an</strong>d for cocoa butter mainly for cosmetics.<br />

It c<strong>an</strong> be expected that the dem<strong>an</strong>d for cocoa will rise over the next years because<br />

cocoa products are luxury products which consume naturally will incre<strong>as</strong>e with<br />

growing st<strong>an</strong>dard of living. [ICCO05] reported that income el<strong>as</strong>ticities of dem<strong>an</strong>d<br />

for cocoa are around 0.85 at world scale, i.e. <strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>e in worlds GDP by 10% cause<br />

<strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>e in worlds dem<strong>an</strong>d for cocoa by 8.5%. Moreover, the study shows that<br />

27 Data source: [The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005] <strong>an</strong>d [ICCO].<br />

24


2.1 The different Commodity Types<br />

world’s dem<strong>an</strong>d for cocoa is negatively correlated to inflation by -0.2. 28 Production<br />

depends on the number <strong>an</strong>d characteristics of the ever green tropic cocoa trees<br />

pl<strong>an</strong>ted 5 to 6 years ago what results in <strong>an</strong> inability to react to unexpected short<br />

term dem<strong>an</strong>d. 29 An other unstable factor in this market is the political situation<br />

of the major producing countries. Cote d’Ivories h<strong>as</strong> just ce<strong>as</strong>ed its civil war but<br />

still, there are political queries what cause a production decre<strong>as</strong>e. In 2007 the cocoa<br />

market is likely be nervous because Africa h<strong>as</strong> to fight against a cocoa moth plague.<br />

2.1.3.2 Grains exemplified by Corn<br />

Corn is a member of the gr<strong>as</strong>s family of pl<strong>an</strong>ts <strong>an</strong>d is a native grain of the Americ<strong>an</strong><br />

continent. About 5,000 BC, it w<strong>as</strong> first cultivated in Central America to use it <strong>as</strong><br />

hum<strong>an</strong> food. The cereal w<strong>as</strong> brought to Europe <strong>an</strong>d North America, but remained<br />

poorly grown until the 19th century. Corn is a resist<strong>an</strong>t pl<strong>an</strong>t only vulnerable to early<br />

frosts in fall that c<strong>an</strong> be grown in different climates r<strong>an</strong>ging from arid to tropical<br />

<strong>an</strong>d in different regions r<strong>an</strong>ging from flat country to mountain side. Today, corn<br />

accounts for about 70% of the world coarse grain trade <strong>an</strong>d about 75% of its yearly<br />

production are used for <strong>an</strong>imal feed. 30 A small amount of around 15% is still used<br />

in hum<strong>an</strong> food mainly for oil <strong>an</strong>d vegetari<strong>an</strong> food <strong>an</strong>d the remaining percentages are<br />

used for alcohol distilleries <strong>an</strong>d the production of eth<strong>an</strong>ol for engines. Latter part<br />

of usage is expected to incre<strong>as</strong>e considerably caused by the high oil prices. Today<br />

around 95% of North America’s eth<strong>an</strong>ol is made from corn. Programs on eth<strong>an</strong>ol<br />

production from corn will therefore have a const<strong>an</strong>t influence on corn prices in the<br />

future. 31<br />

By far the biggest producer worldwide is the USA with around 40% of share of total<br />

world production in 2006. 32 It reached its production high so far in 2004 with a<br />

total output of 300 million tonnes, i.e. 80 million tonnes (= 25%) more th<strong>an</strong> in<br />

2006. Figure 2.12 shows the worldwide development of inventory, production <strong>an</strong>d<br />

consumption <strong>an</strong>d the equivalent year ending prices. 33<br />

Low prices since the end of the 90s have made corn business unattractive <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Figure 2.12 clearly shows that inventories have fallen since then. Calculating the<br />

28 Thus, it c<strong>an</strong> be <strong>as</strong>sumed that a decline in prices of 10% results in <strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>e in dem<strong>an</strong>d of 2%.<br />

29 A single tree c<strong>an</strong> produce 20 fruits but it needs 400 to get one pound of chocolate.<br />

30 See [The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005].<br />

31 See [USDA Grain 2006].<br />

32 Moreover, the USA is the biggest exporter worldwide with around 70% of share of world corn<br />

trade showing world’s corn supply dependence of US production output.<br />

33 See [USDA Grain 2006] <strong>an</strong>d [The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005].<br />

25


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

Figure 2.12: Corn Price, Stock of Inventory, Production <strong>an</strong>d Consumption<br />

stocks <strong>as</strong> percentage of consumption ratio highlights the situation: while at the end<br />

of the 70th, stocks made up around 25% of consumption, they made up around 35%<br />

at the end of the 80th, 30% at the end of the 90th <strong>an</strong>d finally, only 12% in 2006.<br />

Falling production caused by low prices came h<strong>an</strong>d in h<strong>an</strong>d with a growing dem<strong>an</strong>d.<br />

Two major re<strong>as</strong>ons for growing dem<strong>an</strong>d c<strong>an</strong> be identified: the use of corn <strong>as</strong> part of<br />

fuels pulls off a growing part of production <strong>an</strong>d 2006 w<strong>as</strong> the first year, were China<br />

became a net importer of corn <strong>an</strong>d it c<strong>an</strong>not be expected that this situation will turn<br />

around in the next years. While the country’s stock of inventory were around 123<br />

million tonnes at the end of the 90th, they are around 28 million tonnes today. This<br />

environment of low inventories make prices quite vulnerable for supply interruption.<br />

Figure 2.12 also shows that production is more volatile th<strong>an</strong> consumption is. Corn<br />

output depends on stable weather conditions. Consequently, bad weather will lead<br />

to a bad harvest. This will be followed by exploding prices because inventories are<br />

low <strong>an</strong>d c<strong>an</strong> hardly st<strong>an</strong>d a production collapse.<br />

2.1.3.3 Livestock exemplified by Live <strong>an</strong>d Feeder Cattle<br />

The beef cycle begins with the cow-calf operation, which breeds the new calves.<br />

Because the gestation period is about nine month, most r<strong>an</strong>gers breed their herds of<br />

cows in summer, thus processing the new crop of calves in spring. This allows the<br />

calves to be born during mild weather <strong>an</strong>d they c<strong>an</strong> graze through the summer <strong>an</strong>d<br />

early autumn in the open countryside. After 6 - 8 months the calves c<strong>an</strong> be taken<br />

away from their mothers <strong>an</strong>d most of them are then moved into the ”stocker operation”<br />

where they spend 6 - 10 months. When the cattle reached 600 - 800 pounds,<br />

they are typically sent to a feedlot <strong>an</strong>d become the so-called ”feeder cattle”. In the<br />

26


2.1 The different Commodity Types<br />

feedlot, the cattle are fed a special food mix including grain, e.g. corn or wheat, a<br />

protein, e.g. soybe<strong>an</strong>s, <strong>an</strong>d roughage to encourage rapid weight gain. The <strong>an</strong>imal is<br />

considered ”finished” when it reaches full weight typically 1200 pounds. Then it is<br />

sold for slaughter to a meat packing pl<strong>an</strong>t. 34<br />

Because feeder cattle is a downstream product of live cattle it is traded at a premium<br />

<strong>an</strong>d price movements between the two commodities are highly correlated with<br />

a signific<strong>an</strong>t correlation coefficient of 0.53. 35 Figure 2.13 shows live cattle statistics<br />

including prices, inventory, production <strong>an</strong>d consumption.<br />

Figure 2.13: Cattle Price, Stock of Inventory, Production <strong>an</strong>d Consumption<br />

The huge price incre<strong>as</strong>e in 2002 w<strong>as</strong> caused by a decre<strong>as</strong>ing inventory of 30 million<br />

heads worldwide from 2002 to 2003 caused by high feeding costs. But, the total<br />

number of calves (<strong>an</strong>d their age) is not enough to describe supply: the prices of<br />

feed, i.e. of corn, wheat <strong>an</strong>d soybe<strong>an</strong>s, make a big difference since <strong>an</strong>imals are fed<br />

longer if corn is cheap. This pattern c<strong>an</strong> be seen in Figure 2.14 what shows the price<br />

development of feeder cattle <strong>an</strong>d corn.<br />

Unfortunately, over the long run signific<strong>an</strong>t <strong>an</strong>ti - correlation could not be proofed.But<br />

<strong>an</strong>alyzing weekly futures data during the period of 1994 <strong>an</strong>d 2006 a signific<strong>an</strong>t negative<br />

correlation of -0.15 could be found.<br />

34 See [The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005].<br />

35 For the <strong>an</strong>alyzes of this section we took monthly c<strong>as</strong>h data since 1970 of the<br />

[The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005] completed with Bloomberg data for 2005 <strong>an</strong>d 2006.<br />

We used monthly log returns <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.2. For the mathematical definition of Pearson<br />

correlation <strong>an</strong>d the related statistical test see Section 5.1.2.<br />

27


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

Figure 2.14: Dependency of Feeder Cattle <strong>an</strong>d Corn Prices<br />

2.2 Characteristics of Commodity Markets<br />

Commodity markets are in their origin quite different to traditional fin<strong>an</strong>cial markets<br />

for stocks, bonds <strong>an</strong>d currencies. Their major difference is that commodities are<br />

real <strong>as</strong>sets that are produced <strong>an</strong>d consumed in industrial processes <strong>an</strong>d prices are<br />

therefore mainly driven by industrial supply <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d. But the interaction of<br />

supply, dem<strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>d commodity prices interfere with each other, i.e. production <strong>an</strong>d<br />

consumption are price driving but also price driven. If prices are high so-called high<br />

price producers enter the market. A famous example for this phenomena are the<br />

oil s<strong>an</strong>ds in C<strong>an</strong>ada. Current oil prices have reached price levels which enable <strong>an</strong><br />

economic extraction of oil there. On the other h<strong>an</strong>d if prices are high consumers try<br />

to substitute commodities against each other <strong>as</strong> described on Section 2.1.1 the ch<strong>an</strong>ge<br />

from oil to natural g<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong>d other alternative energy sources. Still, commodities are<br />

primarily consumption goods. Dem<strong>an</strong>d is therefore not purely price dependent.<br />

<strong>Commodities</strong> are heterogenous in terms of quality <strong>an</strong>d grade which is reflected in<br />

market prices. This contr<strong>as</strong>ts to traditional <strong>as</strong>set: a dollar is a dollar or a Siemens<br />

stock is a Siemens stock but coffee or cocoa be<strong>an</strong>s are likely to differ in size <strong>an</strong>d<br />

quality. Another major difference to traditional <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses is the se<strong>as</strong>onal pattern<br />

in consumption <strong>an</strong>d production which is m<strong>an</strong>ifested in recurring behavior of prices<br />

<strong>an</strong>d volatility, e.g. prices for agricultural products are influenced by crop times or oil<br />

products prices fluctuate with heating or driving se<strong>as</strong>ons. 36 Putting all differences<br />

together we realize that there are new value dimensions which have to be considered<br />

when it comes to commodity investments:<br />

Prices are supply <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d driven<br />

36 See Appendix B.1 <strong>an</strong>d B.2.<br />

28


2.2 Characteristics of Commodity Markets<br />

Supply <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d limits are not purely price dependent<br />

Timing uncertainly in production <strong>an</strong>d supply<br />

Direct exposure to a variety of exogenous functions, e.g.<br />

environment or technological ch<strong>an</strong>ge<br />

weather, political<br />

Some commodities c<strong>an</strong> be substituted by others<br />

Physical accessability introduces tr<strong>an</strong>sportation <strong>an</strong>d location issues<br />

There are additional costs like storage, insur<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d w<strong>as</strong>tage costs<br />

Difference between storable, e.g. metals, <strong>an</strong>d non storable commodities, e.g. electricity<br />

Complex processing chains, some commodities are downstream commodities of<br />

others, e.g. soybe<strong>an</strong>s are needed to get soybe<strong>an</strong> meal 37 what on its side is needed<br />

for live cattle breeding<br />

<strong>Commodities</strong> market enable global trade. Nevertheless, local constraints have to be<br />

kept in mind including the often high tr<strong>an</strong>sportation costs, costs <strong>an</strong>d risks between<br />

markets (e.g. piracy, ship in distress), industry regulations <strong>an</strong>d currency factors.<br />

Figure 2.15 gives <strong>an</strong> example of a typical processing chain in commodity markets. 38<br />

It covers the major interaction of commodity market members:<br />

Figure 2.15: Commodity Markets Process Chain<br />

37 See Appendix B.11.<br />

38 Inspired by [Structured Products 2006]<br />

29


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

The different particip<strong>an</strong>ts have - caused by their different business purposes - different<br />

risk <strong>an</strong>d return profiles. The actual real <strong>as</strong>set traders are the producers,<br />

processors <strong>an</strong>d consumers. The first goes short the commodity because he w<strong>an</strong>ts to<br />

sell the raw commodity, e.g. crude oil, soybe<strong>an</strong>s or live cattle. The application of<br />

fin<strong>an</strong>cial instruments is frequently driven by the pattern of c<strong>as</strong>h flows. Generally<br />

producers have to make signific<strong>an</strong>t fin<strong>an</strong>cing in adv<strong>an</strong>ce, e.g. a cattlem<strong>an</strong> h<strong>as</strong> to<br />

pay for <strong>an</strong>imal feed, accommodation, medical care etc. to undertake his production.<br />

The live cattle sale some day in the future is exposed to price fluctuations what<br />

makes pl<strong>an</strong>ing uncertainly. If prices decline sharply revenues may fall short to cover<br />

the costs of serving production’s fin<strong>an</strong>cing costs. Hence, there is a natural tendency<br />

for producers to hedge their future sale at price levels that ensure adequate returns<br />

without seeking to optimize the potential returns from higher prices.<br />

Processors have a spread exposure in commodities markets. They have to take care<br />

about the price difference between the cost of input <strong>an</strong>d the cost of the output.<br />

Generally processors try to ensure delivery <strong>an</strong>d enlarge the spread gain. Therefore,<br />

they have to make sure that the inventories are filled up with input commodities<br />

properly to bal<strong>an</strong>ce output dem<strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>d input supply fluctuations.<br />

At the end of the chain is the consumer. He goes long the commodity, i.e. he<br />

w<strong>an</strong>ts to buy it. His hedging behavior is more complex. His desire to undertake<br />

hedges is influenced by the availability of substitute products <strong>an</strong>d the ability to<br />

p<strong>as</strong>s on higher input costs in its own product market. In m<strong>an</strong>y c<strong>as</strong>es there exist<br />

direct bilateral long term supply or purch<strong>as</strong>e contracts between the consumer <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the producer which may include fixed price arr<strong>an</strong>gements to reduce price risk for<br />

both parties. Nevertheless, these agreements include a number of difficulties, e.g.<br />

the lack of tr<strong>an</strong>sparency, lower liquidity <strong>an</strong>d exposure to counterparty credit risk.<br />

Traders <strong>an</strong>d fin<strong>an</strong>cial institutions are the lube of commodities markets. They are<br />

responsible to ensure price formations <strong>an</strong>d enable the actual tr<strong>an</strong>saction. Therefore,<br />

they act <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> agent or principal to secure the sale or purch<strong>as</strong>e of the commodity <strong>an</strong>d<br />

add value to a pure trading relationship by providing risk <strong>an</strong>d portfolio m<strong>an</strong>agement<br />

expertise. Traders have complex hedging requirements depending on their customer<br />

specific role: acting <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> agent a trader generally will have no price exposure but<br />

acting <strong>as</strong> a principal he will generally have outright price risk which need to be<br />

hedged. Globally he h<strong>as</strong> to h<strong>an</strong>dle his client specific risks <strong>an</strong>d hedging requirements<br />

<strong>as</strong> portfolio to enable diversification effects.<br />

To provide commodities markets with fin<strong>an</strong>cing <strong>an</strong>d liquidity, fin<strong>an</strong>cial institutions<br />

are essential. Their role in commodities markets is similar to that in the deriva-<br />

30


2.3 Trading <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

tives markets in other <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses. They provide liquidity improvement, speed of<br />

execution <strong>an</strong>d structural flexibility. Nowadays, their role is becoming more complex<br />

<strong>an</strong>d interdisciplinary. They underst<strong>an</strong>d themselves <strong>as</strong> all fin<strong>an</strong>ce service provider<br />

to feed their clients with structured products. Their interaction with the l<strong>as</strong>t big<br />

particip<strong>an</strong>t group of commodities markets, the investors, is growing strongly.<br />

Investors trade commodities <strong>as</strong> a separate <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d care about their portfolio<br />

risk <strong>an</strong>d return profile to maximize their revenues. For producers they are essential<br />

<strong>as</strong> risk takers whereupon the oldest theory of how commodity prices are build up,<br />

the so-called theory of normal backwardation, 39 is b<strong>as</strong>ed on. Investors never will<br />

hold commodities until delivery. C<strong>as</strong>h settlement or selling before maturity is done.<br />

Investors are necessary for fair price formation, i.e. fin<strong>an</strong>cial markets c<strong>an</strong> only<br />

be efficient when its members reach a critical m<strong>as</strong>s. Different articles 40 , which<br />

<strong>an</strong>alyze the return development of actively m<strong>an</strong>aged commodity portfolios, mention,<br />

that their pure alpha decre<strong>as</strong>ed over time. This pattern indicates that fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

markets become more efficient <strong>an</strong>d arbitrage opportunities are disabled just because<br />

of liquidity <strong>an</strong>d trading volume.<br />

2.3 Trading <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

To cover all the different needs of the market particip<strong>an</strong>ts, a r<strong>an</strong>ge of different<br />

fin<strong>an</strong>cial products enabling both, hedging <strong>an</strong>d speculation, were developed. Unfortunately,<br />

some investors might feel lost in the forest of opportunities. Therefore,<br />

they should first develop a set of requirements that meet their individual investment<br />

needs. Then, they should search <strong>an</strong>d screen <strong>an</strong>d just finally select what will meet<br />

their individual objectives. In the following section the most common commodity<br />

investment vehicles <strong>an</strong>d related products are introduced. For it, Figure 2.16 shall<br />

give a first overview. There are two major ways of investing into commodities: the<br />

direct <strong>an</strong>d the indirect over stocks.<br />

Our main focus lies on the direct way to get commodity exposure.<br />

To be very<br />

precise, it is divided into the direct commodity investment over fin<strong>an</strong>cial products<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the direct commodity investment into the commodity product. But we <strong>as</strong>sume<br />

that no investor is actually interested in camping oil barrels or corn bags in his<br />

b<strong>as</strong>ement, we will focus on the direct commodity investment over fin<strong>an</strong>cial products<br />

without physical delivery. The b<strong>as</strong>ic products are described in Section 2.3.1<br />

39 We will examine the theory of normal backwardation in Section 3.1.<br />

40 See e.g. [Edwards Liew 1999] or [Fung Hiesh 1997].<br />

31


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

Figure 2.16: Overview of Commodity Investment Instruments<br />

<strong>an</strong>d called derivatives including futures, the elementary vehicle to trade raw commodities,<br />

swaps, options linked bonds <strong>an</strong>d certificates. Following, the investment in<br />

commodity portfolios, both actively <strong>an</strong>d p<strong>as</strong>sively m<strong>an</strong>aged ones, are highlighted.<br />

To get actively m<strong>an</strong>aged commodity exposure, <strong>an</strong> investor h<strong>as</strong> to hire a so-called<br />

Commodity Trading Advisor (CTA). The different ways to do so are described in<br />

Section 2.3.2. P<strong>as</strong>sively m<strong>an</strong>aged ones are represented by indices. Exposure c<strong>an</strong> be<br />

taken through index linked products such <strong>as</strong> index tracking investment or exch<strong>an</strong>ge<br />

traded funds. Because the main part of this work will later focus on this investment<br />

vehicle we will dedicate it the whole Section 4. Finally, in Section 2.3.3 we will bring<br />

in mind stocks of commodity producing comp<strong>an</strong>ies, i.e. the indirect commodity investment<br />

way. For m<strong>an</strong>y investors this represents the traditional <strong>an</strong>d familiar way<br />

of taking exposure in commodities markets. Buying stocks or stock funds are <strong>an</strong><br />

uncomplicated long term orientated investment methodology that is not connected<br />

with maturities. But our focus lies on direct commodity investment <strong>an</strong>d therefore,<br />

we will keep this topic short.<br />

2.3.1 Commodity Derivatives<br />

As we have already pointed out, that there are different factors which incre<strong>as</strong>ed the<br />

dem<strong>an</strong>d for commodity related products. The following section describes the different<br />

types of derivatives, i.e. fin<strong>an</strong>cial products which payoff structure depends on the<br />

price process of <strong>an</strong>other fin<strong>an</strong>cial instrument that is commonly used to get <strong>an</strong>d/or<br />

hedge commodity exposure. The main structure in exch<strong>an</strong>ge traded commodity<br />

32


2.3 Trading <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

markets are futures contracts. They are the original vehicle to trade commodities.<br />

Although the price of a futures contract depends on the current spot (c<strong>as</strong>h)<br />

price 41 of the underlying commodity, it represents on its side the underlying of other<br />

derivatives like options, swaps <strong>an</strong>d commodity linked bonds.<br />

M<strong>an</strong>y economists, including Al<strong>an</strong> Greensp<strong>an</strong>, stated that the fin<strong>an</strong>cial derivatives<br />

markets have signific<strong>an</strong>tly decre<strong>as</strong>ed the cost of doing business <strong>an</strong>d thus have risen<br />

the st<strong>an</strong>dard of living for everybody. A major step to this development w<strong>as</strong> done in<br />

the work of Merton Miller, Harry Markowitz <strong>an</strong>d William Sharpe who won the 1990s<br />

Novel Price in economics for recognizing <strong>an</strong>d illustrating the value of derivatives in<br />

business application. 42 Their theoretical conclusions found their way into practical<br />

applications created by Fischer Black, Myron Scholes, Robert Shiller, Rudi Zagst<br />

<strong>an</strong>d m<strong>an</strong>y others.<br />

Today m<strong>an</strong>y fin<strong>an</strong>cial intermediaries, including domestic <strong>an</strong>d international b<strong>an</strong>ks,<br />

public <strong>an</strong>d private pension funds, investment comp<strong>an</strong>ies, mutual funds, hedge funds,<br />

energy providers, <strong>as</strong>set <strong>an</strong>d liability m<strong>an</strong>agers, mortgage comp<strong>an</strong>ies, swap dealers,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d insur<strong>an</strong>ce comp<strong>an</strong>ies, that face foreign exch<strong>an</strong>ge, energy, agricultural or environmental<br />

exposure use fin<strong>an</strong>cial markets to hedge or m<strong>an</strong>age their price risk. For<br />

inst<strong>an</strong>ce, at the Chicago Merc<strong>an</strong>tile Exch<strong>an</strong>ge (CME) more th<strong>an</strong> one billion contracts<br />

representing <strong>an</strong> underlying notional value of 640 trillion US dollar were traded<br />

<strong>an</strong>d cleared in 2005. 43<br />

2.3.1.1 Forwards <strong>an</strong>d Futures<br />

A forward contract is a bilateral agreement where one party is going to buy <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set<br />

at a today predefined time in the future for a fixed price. Hereby someone c<strong>an</strong> be<br />

long or short the contract depending on the fact whether he took the <strong>as</strong>set buyer<br />

or seller position.<br />

Forwards were originally developed to hedge commodity price<br />

risk <strong>an</strong>d are useful vehicles to look at future prices. As described in Section 2.2<br />

commodity producers need to ensure future c<strong>as</strong>h flows to be cost covering. First<br />

applications of forwards go back in the 18th <strong>an</strong>d 19th centuries. Potato growers in<br />

the state of Maine (USA) started selling their crops at the time of pl<strong>an</strong>ting in order to<br />

fin<strong>an</strong>ce the production process. Such arr<strong>an</strong>gements became particularly import<strong>an</strong>t<br />

41 For the feature of spot prices in commodity markets see the discussion in Section 5.1.1.<br />

42 William Sharpe w<strong>as</strong> rewarded for the Capital <strong>Asset</strong> Pricing Model, beta <strong>an</strong>d relative risks, Harry<br />

Markowitz for his theory of efficient portfolio selection <strong>an</strong>d Merton Miller for his work on the<br />

effect of a firm’s capital structure <strong>an</strong>d dividend policy on market price.<br />

43 Data source: Futures Industry Magazine Mar/Apr 2006, numbers include fin<strong>an</strong>cial derivatives<br />

(i.e. derivatives on interest rates or equities)<br />

33


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

in industries where non influenceable external factors like weather conditions are of<br />

high import<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d the production process is cost intensive.<br />

The first established emporiums where in terms of qu<strong>an</strong>tity, quality <strong>an</strong>d delivery<br />

date st<strong>an</strong>dardized forward contracts, so-called future contracts, were traded, are<br />

the New York Cotton Exch<strong>an</strong>ge (NYCE), founded 1842, <strong>an</strong>d the Chicago Board of<br />

Trade (CBOT), founded 1848.<br />

Although forwards <strong>an</strong>d futures on the same underlying with the same time to expiry<br />

have the same original spirit ”sell <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set today but deliver it tomorrow” they are<br />

different in m<strong>an</strong>y counts, including tr<strong>an</strong>saction costs, credit risk, 44 customization<br />

<strong>an</strong>d stoch<strong>as</strong>tic interest rate. The most noticeable difference between futures <strong>an</strong>d<br />

forwards is that futures are marked-to-market daily <strong>an</strong>d their particip<strong>an</strong>ts have to<br />

adjust their positions on the so-called margin account which introduces <strong>an</strong> additional<br />

re-investment risk: while the profit or loss of a forward contract occurs at the<br />

maturity date, the profits <strong>an</strong>d losses of futures contracts are spread over the live of<br />

the contract <strong>an</strong>d occur on a daily b<strong>as</strong>is. For inst<strong>an</strong>ce, if a particip<strong>an</strong>t h<strong>as</strong> a long<br />

position in a futures contract which price went down from one day to the next, then<br />

he gets the so-called margin call from the clearing house st<strong>an</strong>ding behind the respective<br />

exch<strong>an</strong>ge what requests him to c<strong>as</strong>h settle the difference on the so-called margin<br />

account. From this point of view a future is a series of daily settled forwards <strong>an</strong>d<br />

its value over the whole period is the net present value (NPV) of the single margin<br />

calls. If interest rates are not stoch<strong>as</strong>tic the NPV equals the NPV of a forward over<br />

the whole period. 45 If interest rates are stoch<strong>as</strong>tic the futures price is greater or less<br />

th<strong>an</strong> the forward price depending on the correlation of interest rates <strong>an</strong>d the commodity<br />

spot price. If they are positively correlated (what in theory should be the<br />

c<strong>as</strong>e because commodities are real <strong>as</strong>sets) daily payments from price incre<strong>as</strong>es will<br />

on average be more heavily discounted th<strong>an</strong> payments from price decre<strong>as</strong>es, so the<br />

initial futures price must exceed the forward price. 46 However, studies have shown,<br />

that the difference is typically small.<br />

[Pindyck 1994] compared one-month heating<br />

oil contracts <strong>an</strong>d estimated the difference being less th<strong>an</strong> 0.01%. [French 1983]<br />

compared the futures prices of three month silver <strong>an</strong>d copper contracts with their<br />

equivalent forward prices <strong>an</strong>d found that the difference is about 0.1%. Therefore, it<br />

is common not to differentiate between forward <strong>an</strong>d futures prices. We will do so,<br />

too.<br />

44 Because forward contracts are over the counter (OTC) bilateral agreements they embody counterparty<br />

default risks.<br />

45 For the formal mathematical proof that forward <strong>an</strong>d futures prices are equal under the <strong>as</strong>sumption<br />

of deterministic interest rates see [Zagst 2002].<br />

46 For further information see [Cox Ross Ingersoll 1981]<br />

34


2.3 Trading <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

Historically, the expiration months of futures contracts were without some exceptions<br />

March, June, September <strong>an</strong>d December reflecting the se<strong>as</strong>onality in commodities<br />

markets. This h<strong>as</strong> ch<strong>an</strong>ged with growing markets. Today there are contracts<br />

for every delivery month <strong>an</strong>d long term maturities until 5 years available.<br />

As we mentioned introductory, futures trading h<strong>as</strong> grown rapidly. For inst<strong>an</strong>ce, the<br />

New York Merc<strong>an</strong>tile Exch<strong>an</strong>ge (NYMEX) Crude Oil Future is me<strong>an</strong>while listed<br />

under the 20th most often traded future contracts worldwide with a trading volume<br />

of over 50 million contracts in 2005. This w<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>e of around 15%. Its main<br />

competitor Brent crude oil futures contract, follows with clear dist<strong>an</strong>ce. Although<br />

its trading volume went up 17% in 2005 it only could reach a volume of 25 million<br />

traded contracts. Over this electronic trading is coming up what will additionally<br />

boost trading volume in the next years. 47<br />

The metals markets showed the same picture. The trading of gold at the NYMEX<br />

went up over 6% in 2005 to approximately 13 million traded contracts. The London<br />

Metal Exch<strong>an</strong>ge (LME) surp<strong>as</strong>sed Sh<strong>an</strong>ghai with the most copper futures traded<br />

worldwide, with volume up approximately 4% to over 16 million.<br />

The agricultural trading h<strong>as</strong> grown <strong>as</strong> well. Surprisingly, putting future <strong>an</strong>d option<br />

contracts in volume together it h<strong>as</strong> the highest trading volume of all commodity<br />

groups. Although the Asi<strong>an</strong> trading volume went down in 2005 the US exch<strong>an</strong>ges<br />

registered strong incre<strong>as</strong>es: the Chicago Board of Trade (CBOT) corn future went<br />

up 14% to over 23 million traded contracts, the CBOT wheat future went up 25% to<br />

over 8 million traded contracts <strong>an</strong>d the New York Board of Trade sugar #1 future<br />

went up 20% to over 12 million traded contracts.<br />

2.3.1.2 Options<br />

Commodity options are options where the underlying <strong>as</strong>set is a commodity or commodity<br />

index. In contr<strong>as</strong>t to futures contracts they certify the right but not the<br />

duty to buy or sell <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set at some future point.<br />

Commodity options are identical to options on traditional <strong>as</strong>sets such <strong>as</strong> stocks <strong>an</strong>d<br />

are primary used to m<strong>an</strong>age risk or to generate premium income through <strong>as</strong>ymmetric<br />

risk exposure. Nowadays, stock options are more common th<strong>an</strong> commodity options.<br />

Nevertheless the options concept w<strong>as</strong> originally developed in commodity markets.<br />

First historical traditions go back to the mathematici<strong>an</strong>, philosopher <strong>an</strong>d <strong>as</strong>tronomer<br />

47 Data source: Futures Industry Magazine J<strong>an</strong>/Feb 2006<br />

35


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

Tales. In expectation of a good olive harvest he bought the right to use olive<br />

squeezing machines. In the 17th century options were introduced in the Netherl<strong>an</strong>ds<br />

to trade tulips, but the first st<strong>an</strong>dardized options exch<strong>an</strong>ge, the Chicago Board<br />

Option Exch<strong>an</strong>ge, w<strong>as</strong> founded not until 1973. Together with the in the same year<br />

published fundamental Black/Scholes option pricing model this w<strong>as</strong> the starting<br />

shoot for professional fin<strong>an</strong>cial option trading.<br />

The available st<strong>an</strong>dard forms are call <strong>an</strong>d put options. The former are buy options:<br />

the holder of the option h<strong>as</strong> the right to buy the underlying at a predefined price <strong>an</strong>d<br />

time in future. A put option is a sell option: the holder of the option h<strong>as</strong> the right<br />

to sell the underlying at a predefined price <strong>an</strong>d time in future. In addition to the<br />

st<strong>an</strong>dard forms there are cap <strong>an</strong>d floor options over the counter (OTC) available. A<br />

cap is a series of call options <strong>an</strong>d a floor is a series of put options on the commodity<br />

itself. They are commonly used to m<strong>an</strong>age ongoing price exposure to the underlying<br />

commodity. Exch<strong>an</strong>ge traded options are exercised into a position of the underlying<br />

commodity future contract which is either c<strong>as</strong>h or physically settled. OTC options<br />

are mainly c<strong>as</strong>h settled directly.<br />

Option trading h<strong>as</strong> grown <strong>as</strong> futures trading did. The LME copper future registered<br />

a trading volume incre<strong>as</strong>e of approximately 13% to nearby 2 million contracts<br />

in 2005. Only precious metals options trading is <strong>an</strong> exception. The New York<br />

Merc<strong>an</strong>tile Exch<strong>an</strong>ge reported a decre<strong>as</strong>e of gold option trading of over 40%.<br />

However, heavy trading is reported about the NYMEX crude oil option. Its trading<br />

volume went up over 30% to over 12 million contracts. Together with the NYMEX<br />

crude oil futures trading volume this counts for approximately one quarter of global<br />

energy futures <strong>an</strong>d options trading. 48<br />

Putting commodity futures <strong>an</strong>d options trading together it counts for a trading<br />

volume of over 620 million contracts in 2005. Comparing this number with other<br />

market’s trading volumes exp<strong>an</strong>sion potential c<strong>an</strong> be suspected: the equity indices<br />

futures <strong>an</strong>d options trading volume counts for over 3.4 billion contracts <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

derivatives trading of individual equities for <strong>an</strong>other 2 billion, followed by the interest<br />

rate market with over 2.1 billion traded futures <strong>an</strong>d options contracts in 2005.<br />

48 Data source: Futures Industry Magazine J<strong>an</strong>/Feb 2006<br />

36


2.3 Trading <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

2.3.1.3 Swaps<br />

Commodity swaps are generally the same like interest rate swaps 49 with the difference<br />

that the underlying payment streams are linked to the price movement of<br />

a commodity. A swap is <strong>an</strong> agreement between two parties to regularly exch<strong>an</strong>ge<br />

payments. The most common type is the fixed-for-floating commodity swap. The<br />

buyer of the swap pays at predefined usually equally spaced dates t 1 , . . . , t n a fixed<br />

price for a commodity times the notional <strong>an</strong>d receives from the seller of the swap<br />

the market value of the commodity times the notional. Hereby the notional is given<br />

in commodity units, e.g. tones of grain or barrels of oil. Figure 2.17 illustrates the<br />

exch<strong>an</strong>ge of payments at the oil market.<br />

Figure 2.17: Commodity Swap Payment Streams<br />

In order to hedge his cost structure a crude oil consumer such <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> heating oil<br />

refiner enters into the described swap <strong>as</strong> the fixed leg, e.g. he is going to pay a fixed<br />

price for crude oil times the notional at predefined dates. Generally, he will expect<br />

oil prices to rise. On the other h<strong>an</strong>d of the swap st<strong>an</strong>ds the producer of oil, e.g. the<br />

oil extraction comp<strong>an</strong>y. It c<strong>an</strong> be expected that its fin<strong>an</strong>cial m<strong>an</strong>agement forec<strong>as</strong>ts a<br />

price decre<strong>as</strong>e <strong>an</strong>d w<strong>an</strong>ts to sell its product to a price fixed on the current high level.<br />

In vocabularies of c<strong>as</strong>h settlement e.g. he is going to pay the floating (respective<br />

market) price times the notional. Usually, just the net positions are c<strong>as</strong>h settled.<br />

Generally, <strong>as</strong> described under Section 2.2, producer <strong>an</strong>d consumer do not act directly<br />

with each other but traders m<strong>an</strong>age to bring the adequate parties together. We<br />

have seen that the side of the swap entered by a party depends on its expectation of<br />

ongoing price developments. Because m<strong>an</strong>y commodity swaps are c<strong>as</strong>h settled today,<br />

investors c<strong>an</strong> speculate on their expectation through entering into the respective side<br />

of a swap instead of entering into a series of the respective futures contracts. Out of<br />

the investors point of view <strong>an</strong> adv<strong>an</strong>tage of swaps is the long term orientation <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the absence of rolling maturing futures contracts.<br />

Swaps c<strong>an</strong> e<strong>as</strong>ily be used in structured products where the exch<strong>an</strong>ge of different<br />

49 For a general introduction to interest rate swaps see [Zagst 2002]<br />

37


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

types of c<strong>as</strong>h payments are enabled, i.e. someone could think about a price-forinterest<br />

swap. Insur<strong>an</strong>ce comp<strong>an</strong>ies or other institutional investors that wish to<br />

carry a commodity exposure, without being allowed by its regulatory body, may<br />

do so by entering i.e. a price-for-interest swap with a party that is allowed to take<br />

direct commodity exposure, i.e. a b<strong>an</strong>k.<br />

2.3.1.4 Commodity Linked Structured Notes<br />

Commodity linked structured notes are engineered to give investors commodity exposure<br />

through <strong>an</strong> interest rate security where a commodity derivative is embedded.<br />

The issuer of the structured note h<strong>as</strong> no commodity exposure itself. In fact, he is<br />

connected to a commodity desk or dealer which provides the relev<strong>an</strong>t commodity<br />

return c<strong>as</strong>h flows <strong>as</strong> shown in Figure 2.18.<br />

Figure 2.18: Commodity Linked Structured Notes<br />

B<strong>as</strong>ically, there are three different types of commodity linked structured notes: Commodity<br />

forward linked notes, commodity option b<strong>as</strong>ed notes <strong>an</strong>d commodity index<br />

b<strong>as</strong>ed notes. These instruments generally are designed in two ways: either the final<br />

payment or the coupon payments for the lo<strong>an</strong> are commodity linked. The former<br />

one is constructed <strong>as</strong> a zero coupon bond with a notional linked to a commodity, i.e.<br />

the notional is calculated <strong>as</strong> 100% plus/minus a return realized through the linked<br />

commodity. The latter one is constructed <strong>as</strong> a coupon bond where a fixed coupon is<br />

negotiated <strong>an</strong>d it is up or down graded depending on the realized commodity return.<br />

Because the trader h<strong>as</strong> to ensure a fully collateralized commodity investment, the<br />

structured note still includes <strong>an</strong> interest component.<br />

Commodity linked structured notes become more <strong>an</strong>d more popular because m<strong>an</strong>y<br />

investors already know structured notes from equity markets <strong>an</strong>d do not need to care<br />

about rolling futures <strong>an</strong>d credit risk. Investors seeking exposure to commodities are<br />

generally not comfortable with the credit risk of commodity producers. Linked notes<br />

demerge the w<strong>an</strong>ted commodity price risk from the unfavored credit risk <strong>as</strong>pects of<br />

such tr<strong>an</strong>sactions because they are usually offered by high credit grade issuers. Over<br />

38


2.3 Trading <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

this, they are designed to meet investors needs <strong>an</strong>d separate them from commodity<br />

producer <strong>an</strong>d consumer requirements.<br />

Finally a regulatory ch<strong>an</strong>ge in commodity mutual fund markets will force the dem<strong>an</strong>d<br />

for commodity linked interest rate securities.<br />

2.3.1.5 Certificates<br />

A common vehicle to get commodity index exposure in Europe are certificates.<br />

Formally they securitize <strong>an</strong> obligation of the issuer with a regularly claim for interest<br />

coupon payments. That me<strong>an</strong>s that the investor does not purch<strong>as</strong>e stocks or shares<br />

of a mutual fund, he simply lends his money to the issuer. Certificates generally<br />

replicate the price evolvement of <strong>an</strong> underlying stock or index <strong>an</strong>d therefore count<br />

into the group of derivatives. A major characteristic of derivatives is to have a<br />

maturity: so do certificates. Nowadays, there are open-end versions, which include<br />

<strong>an</strong> internal rolling mech<strong>an</strong>ism. 50<br />

Certificates emerge the whole credit risk of the issuer what makes them <strong>an</strong> unattractive<br />

investment vehicle for institutional investors but they are very famous in retail<br />

business. The drawbacks of covered overpricing <strong>an</strong>d credit risk are little communicated.<br />

But their major adv<strong>an</strong>tage is high liquidity. Over this, certificates are generally<br />

available in m<strong>an</strong>y customized versions including refunding conditions equipped<br />

with guar<strong>an</strong>tees, bonuses, caps <strong>an</strong>d/or currency risk hedging facilities. Following<br />

[Zagst e.a. 2006] they c<strong>an</strong> be a perform<strong>an</strong>ce incre<strong>as</strong>ing addition to traditional stock<br />

<strong>an</strong>d bond retail portfolios.<br />

2.3.2 M<strong>an</strong>aged Futures Funds<br />

M<strong>an</strong>aged futures funds are m<strong>an</strong>aged by commodity trading advisors (CTAs). These<br />

trading advisors m<strong>an</strong>age client’s <strong>as</strong>sets by using global futures markets <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> investment<br />

medium. This is the main difference between a CTA <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> ordinary trader.<br />

Former have research b<strong>as</strong>ed investment strategies, including diversification over different<br />

markets, risk m<strong>an</strong>aging <strong>an</strong>d loss limiting systems whereby ordinary traders<br />

generally are generally just experts in one market. In contr<strong>as</strong>t to traders, who are<br />

usually 100% in the market, CTA’s mainly just invest 10-25% of the <strong>as</strong>sets under<br />

m<strong>an</strong>agement to absorb losses while waiting for profitable trades. 51<br />

50 See [Gong Huber L<strong>an</strong>zinner 2006].<br />

51 See M<strong>an</strong>aged Account Research, Inc.;<br />

http : \ \ www.ma − research.com \ m<strong>an</strong>aged account vs self − directed.html<br />

39


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

Investment m<strong>an</strong>agement professionals have been working with m<strong>an</strong>aged futures<br />

funds for more th<strong>an</strong> 30 years. But not until 2000 a broad r<strong>an</strong>ge of institutional<br />

<strong>an</strong>d retail investors seek to invest into m<strong>an</strong>aged futures accounts. The steady dem<strong>an</strong>d<br />

forced industry to grow from about 40 billion US dollar under m<strong>an</strong>agement<br />

in 2001 to about 130 billion US dollar under m<strong>an</strong>agement in 2005. 52 The growing<br />

use of m<strong>an</strong>aged futures by investors may be due to the incre<strong>as</strong>ed institutional use<br />

of the futures markets. Portfolio m<strong>an</strong>agers have become more familiar with futures<br />

contracts. Additionally, investors w<strong>an</strong>t greater diversity in their portfolios. They<br />

seek to incre<strong>as</strong>e portfolio exposure to international investments <strong>an</strong>d non-fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

sectors, <strong>an</strong> objective that is e<strong>as</strong>ily accomplished through the use of global futures<br />

markets.<br />

There are three types of m<strong>an</strong>aged commodity funds available: First, <strong>an</strong> investor<br />

c<strong>an</strong> directly open <strong>an</strong> individually m<strong>an</strong>aged futures account <strong>an</strong>d hire a CTA to m<strong>an</strong>age<br />

his funds b<strong>as</strong>ed on the trading strategy presented in the advisors disclosure<br />

document. The CTA opens <strong>an</strong> individual account on behalf of the investor, enables<br />

him to monitor the activities at <strong>an</strong>y time <strong>an</strong>d his trading authorization c<strong>an</strong><br />

be revoked whenever the investor does not see his interests represented. Therefore,<br />

this type of participation allows investors the most tr<strong>an</strong>sparency <strong>an</strong>d liquidity. Because<br />

most advisors have minimum required investments that r<strong>an</strong>ge from 25,000 to<br />

10 million US dollar this fin<strong>an</strong>cial investment is open only for investors with subst<strong>an</strong>tial<br />

net worth. Second, <strong>an</strong> investor c<strong>an</strong> place his <strong>as</strong>sets at a commodity pool<br />

operator (CTO), who pools funds of different individual investors together <strong>an</strong>d employs<br />

one or more CTAs to m<strong>an</strong>age the pooled funds. Obtaining information about<br />

this private pools is difficult because they are short in advertising to the public.<br />

Their minimum investment requirements r<strong>an</strong>ge from 25,000 to 250,000 US dollar.<br />

Third, <strong>an</strong> investor c<strong>an</strong> purch<strong>as</strong>e the shares of public commodity funds or pools what<br />

is similar to buying shares in a stock or bond mutual fund, except that mutual funds<br />

buy <strong>an</strong>d sell securities rather th<strong>an</strong> commodity futures. Therefore, public funds enable<br />

small retail investors to participate in commodity markets. Within these groups<br />

there is a wide variety of choices among available m<strong>an</strong>aged programs differing from<br />

each other by style, strategy <strong>an</strong>d market focus. In contr<strong>as</strong>t to general advertisement<br />

of the business, research h<strong>as</strong> shown, that m<strong>an</strong>y CTA’s practise a trend following<br />

or opportunistic dynamic trading strategy. For inst<strong>an</strong>ce, [Fung Hiesh 1997] investigated<br />

in over 300 CTA’s during the period 1987 <strong>an</strong>d 1995. [Schneeweiss 2000]<br />

crossed a Rubicon in <strong>an</strong>alyzing CTA portfolios. He reported that ”in general the<br />

52 See M<strong>an</strong>aged Account Research, Inc.;<br />

http : \ \ www.ma − research.com \ growth of m<strong>an</strong>aged futures.html<br />

40


2.3 Trading <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

correlation of CTA strategies with other CTA strategies is dependent on the degree<br />

to which the strategies are trend following or discretionary.” Nevertheless, he showed<br />

that adding m<strong>an</strong>aged futures to a stock <strong>an</strong>d bond portfolio influences the portfolios<br />

risk <strong>an</strong>d return profile positively. We c<strong>an</strong> find a similar statement in [CBOT 2003]<br />

<strong>an</strong>d [Edwards Liew 1999]. Latter investigated in individual CTAs accounts, private<br />

<strong>an</strong>d public commodity funds, <strong>an</strong>d equally <strong>an</strong>d dollar weighted portfolios created out<br />

of individual CTA accounts over the period 1982 <strong>an</strong>d 1996. They found that portfolios<br />

<strong>as</strong> a st<strong>an</strong>d alone investment are much better of th<strong>an</strong> individual accounts <strong>an</strong>d<br />

private or public funds. An interesting observation is that the returns of m<strong>an</strong>aged<br />

futures went down over the l<strong>as</strong>t decade. With more capital <strong>an</strong>d traders competing<br />

for trading profits, commodity markets have become more efficient resulting<br />

in lower returns. The latest Monthly R<strong>an</strong>king Report of [ma-research 052006] h<strong>as</strong><br />

shown dramatic developments. The average yearly returns after fee went down from<br />

over 25% in 1996 to approximately 5% in 2006 so far, what implicates the absence<br />

of arbitrage opportunities occurring in inefficient illiquid markets.<br />

2.3.3 Stocks of Commodity Producing Comp<strong>an</strong>ies<br />

A traditional stock <strong>an</strong>d bond investor c<strong>an</strong> go the indirect way to invest in commodities<br />

by taking exposure in commodity producing comp<strong>an</strong>ies. There exists a<br />

large number of sector indices which are used <strong>as</strong> benchmarks for a v<strong>as</strong>t amount of<br />

sector funds, e.g. the MSCI World Index series offers amongst others the MSCI<br />

World Energy Index which represents the perform<strong>an</strong>ce of a broad b<strong>as</strong>ket of international<br />

acting comp<strong>an</strong>ies in the oil sector, the MSCI World Metals <strong>an</strong>d Mining Index<br />

which represents the perform<strong>an</strong>ce of international comp<strong>an</strong>ies which do business in<br />

the metals mining sector or the MSCI World Food Products which represents the<br />

perform<strong>an</strong>ce of international comp<strong>an</strong>ies active in the food producing business. If<br />

<strong>an</strong> investor w<strong>an</strong>ts to go indirectly into a single commodity or commodity group<br />

over stocks, he c<strong>an</strong> compare SIC codes 53 to find the optimal fitting comp<strong>an</strong>y, e.g.<br />

there are around 300 stocks of energy producing comp<strong>an</strong>ies with the SIC code 1310<br />

or 1311 ”crude petroleum <strong>an</strong>d g<strong>as</strong> extraction” listed at the Americ<strong>an</strong> stock exch<strong>an</strong>ges.<br />

54<br />

This methodology w<strong>as</strong> taken by [Gorton Rouwenhorst 2004] to create<br />

<strong>an</strong> index which replicates their artificially constructed equally weighted commodity<br />

index 55 with commodity producing comp<strong>an</strong>ies. They showed that the cumulated<br />

stock perform<strong>an</strong>ce w<strong>as</strong> less th<strong>an</strong> the cumulated perform<strong>an</strong>ce of the commodities.<br />

53 The St<strong>an</strong>dard Industrial Cl<strong>as</strong>sification Code (SIC) indicates the comp<strong>an</strong>y’s type of business.<br />

54 See <strong>an</strong>d further information: [Gorton Rouwenhorst 2004].<br />

55 For further information about different index weighting procedures see Section 4.1.<br />

41


2 Overview of Commodity Markets<br />

Over this there w<strong>as</strong> a higher correlation (0.57) between the commodity producing<br />

comp<strong>an</strong>ies stock index <strong>an</strong>d the S&P500 th<strong>an</strong> the correlation (0.4) between the<br />

commodity producing comp<strong>an</strong>ies stock index <strong>an</strong>d their equivalent raw commodity<br />

index.<br />

Below we are going to take our own view on commodity producing comp<strong>an</strong>ies. As<br />

<strong>an</strong> example we picked the gold market. Figure 2.19 shows the perform<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

correlations between the Goldm<strong>an</strong> Sachs Futures Gold Index, the HUI Index <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the S&P 500. 56<br />

Figure 2.19: Comparison of Gold <strong>an</strong>d Gold Mining Comp<strong>an</strong>ies<br />

The Goldm<strong>an</strong> Sachs Futures Gold Index represents a futures index which is constructed<br />

by rolling long gold futures contracts from the maturing to the next nearby<br />

futures contract in J<strong>an</strong>uary, March, May July <strong>an</strong>d November of each year. Therefore,<br />

it represents a long only investment in short term gold exposure. The Amex<br />

Gold BUGS (B<strong>as</strong>ket of Unhedged Gold Stocks) Index, known <strong>as</strong> HUI Index, is a<br />

modified equal dollar weighted index of comp<strong>an</strong>ies involved in gold mining. The<br />

HUI Index w<strong>as</strong> designed to provide signific<strong>an</strong>t exposure to near term movements in<br />

gold prices by including comp<strong>an</strong>ies that do not hedge their gold production beyond<br />

1.5 years. We found this index to be representative for a portfolio of gold producing<br />

comp<strong>an</strong>ies which c<strong>as</strong>h flows are highly correlated to nearby gold price movements.<br />

The perform<strong>an</strong>ce chart of Figure 2.19 shows that there is no consistent truth whether<br />

raw commodities or commodity producing comp<strong>an</strong>ies were better off in the l<strong>as</strong>t<br />

years. Gold producing comp<strong>an</strong>ies performed better th<strong>an</strong> gold itself. Over this<br />

56 There were daily Bloomberg data taken <strong>an</strong>d returns were calculated following Definition C.2 <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the plotted price series starting with 100 in 1999 following Definition C.3.<br />

42


2.3 Trading <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

the return correlations 57 behaved quite different to the observations reported by<br />

[Gorton Rouwenhorst 2004]. The correlation of daily log returns between the GS<br />

Gold Futures Index <strong>an</strong>d the HUI Index is signific<strong>an</strong>t with 0.94 <strong>an</strong>d the correlation<br />

of daily log returns between the HUI Index <strong>an</strong>d the S&P 500 Total Return Index is<br />

signific<strong>an</strong>t with -0.25. Over this, the HUI Index is much more volatile th<strong>an</strong> the GS<br />

Gold Futures Index. A HUI Index investor 58 had to accept a yearly average st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

deviation of 42.7% in comparison to a GS Gold Futures Index investor who merely<br />

had to accept 16.2% st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation. Therefore, the main question to <strong>an</strong>swer is<br />

what kind of exposure <strong>an</strong> investor w<strong>an</strong>ts: one in raw commodities, <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s<br />

which is driven by its own risk factors, or one in stocks.<br />

57 See Definition C.2, Definition 5.1 <strong>an</strong>d Equation (5.5).<br />

58 For further information which products are available to invest in <strong>an</strong> index see Section 4.3.<br />

43


3 Pricing of Commodity Futures<br />

Futures prices are the result of open <strong>an</strong>d competitive trading on the floors of exch<strong>an</strong>ges<br />

<strong>an</strong>d, <strong>as</strong> such, tr<strong>an</strong>slate the underlying supply <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d or, rather, their<br />

expected values at various points in future into absolute figures.<br />

Reflecting expectations<br />

about future supply <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d, futures prices trigger decisions about<br />

storage, production <strong>an</strong>d consumption that reallocate the supply <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d for<br />

commodities over time. Social welfare is incre<strong>as</strong>ed by the avoid<strong>an</strong>ce of disruption<br />

in the flow of goods <strong>an</strong>d services. In the c<strong>as</strong>e of storable commodities, these prices<br />

determine the storage decisions of market particip<strong>an</strong>ts: higher futures prices signal<br />

the need for greater storage <strong>an</strong>d lower futures prices point to a reduction in current<br />

inventory. Therefore, commodity futures do not represent a pure fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>set <strong>an</strong>d<br />

traditional no-arbitrage <strong>as</strong>set pricing 59 c<strong>an</strong>not be used to value commodity futures:<br />

Since consumption <strong>an</strong>d processing of the commodity c<strong>an</strong> drive down inventories to<br />

zero, it is not always possible to construct a replicating portfolio for the futures contract.<br />

The second factor why commodity futures c<strong>an</strong>not be valued like pure fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

<strong>as</strong>sets is the non existence of pure spot prices. Although there do exist c<strong>as</strong>h prices<br />

which are actual tr<strong>an</strong>saction prices, c<strong>as</strong>h prices often do not pertain to the same<br />

specification of the commodity compared to a respective futures contract’s specifications<br />

in terms of location, grade <strong>an</strong>d quality. In addition c<strong>as</strong>h prices usually include<br />

discounts <strong>an</strong>d premiums that result from longst<strong>an</strong>ding relationships between buyer<br />

<strong>an</strong>d seller. Therefore, c<strong>as</strong>h prices c<strong>an</strong>not be used <strong>as</strong> a spot price what is directly<br />

comparable to the futures price. A common technique to estimate spot prices out<br />

of futures prices is <strong>an</strong> extrapolation of the spread between the nearest <strong>an</strong>d next-tonearest<br />

active futures contract on a daily b<strong>as</strong>is <strong>as</strong> described in [Pindyck 1994]. The<br />

use of the nearest-to-maturity future price <strong>as</strong> a proxy for the spot price is common<br />

<strong>as</strong> well <strong>an</strong>d described in [Markert 2005] or [Gorton Rouwenhorst 2004]. Because this<br />

technique is used in the construction of the broad indices introduced in Section 4.2<br />

we will follow this procedure <strong>as</strong> well.<br />

Summing up, commodity prices are a mixture of the prices of <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set, reflecting<br />

expectations of future spot prices <strong>an</strong>d the expected risk premium <strong>an</strong>d consumption<br />

good’s prices, reflecting the current scarcity of a good. Depending on either view,<br />

two general futures pricing models were derived: the Risk Premium <strong>an</strong>d the Convenience<br />

Yield Model which we will present in Section 3.1 <strong>an</strong>d Section 3.2.<br />

relationship between the two models were first derived in [Markert 2005] <strong>an</strong>d will be<br />

59 For a general introduction to the concept of no-arbitrage pricing <strong>an</strong>d the related definitions<br />

see [Zagst 2002]. The pioneer work summarizing the different concepts of commodity futures<br />

pricing w<strong>as</strong> done by [Markert 2005].<br />

The<br />

44


3.1 The Risk Premium Model<br />

shown in Section 3.3. The presented models are deterministic <strong>an</strong>d used by traders to<br />

calculate a fair futures price depending on their individual market observations <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the resulting valuations of the input variables. The actual price at which trading<br />

takes place is then generated when seller <strong>an</strong>d buyer prices coincide. But especially<br />

for risk m<strong>an</strong>agement purposes exogenous stoch<strong>as</strong>tic models are needed to simulate<br />

market prices what implicates the ability of portfolio modeling in different market<br />

situations <strong>an</strong>d the observability of the portfolio value in different economic scenarios.<br />

Therefore, mathematici<strong>an</strong>s pick one or more input factors of the pricing formula<br />

<strong>an</strong>d <strong>as</strong>sign a stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process following a certain distribution to them. The actual<br />

market prices are further fitted over special error minimization procedures, e.g. the<br />

Kalm<strong>an</strong> filter, to choose the model parameters properly. Only stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Convenience<br />

Yield Models became widely accepted. We will present the most known ones<br />

in Section 3.4. Starting with simple one factor models in Section 3.4.1, we will further<br />

discuss two factor models in Section 3.4.2, <strong>an</strong>d closing this section with a brief<br />

introduction of three factor models in Section 3.4.3.<br />

3.1 The Risk Premium Model<br />

The Risk Premium Model values commodity futures contracts with respect to the<br />

expected commodity spot price discounted by <strong>an</strong> appropriate risk premium. The<br />

idea behind this approach goes back to Keynes’ theory of normal backwardation. 60<br />

We have already seen in Section 2.2 that there are different market particip<strong>an</strong>ts with<br />

different purposes. To get a deeper insight of their motivations <strong>an</strong>d interactions the<br />

famous example of the cattlem<strong>an</strong> is told: Imagine it is February <strong>an</strong>d there is a<br />

cattlem<strong>an</strong> who w<strong>an</strong>ts to hedge the value of his live cattle in September when the<br />

herd is ready to sell.<br />

of tomorrow over futures contracts. 61<br />

A convenient way to do so is selling today his production<br />

Since futures markets are <strong>as</strong>sumed to be<br />

efficient all market particip<strong>an</strong>ts are <strong>as</strong>sumed to have the same expectation of the<br />

cattle price in September, say 72 cents per pound. However, this price is uncertain<br />

<strong>an</strong>d a variety of events could occur, e.g. heavy barbecuing se<strong>as</strong>on, fear of mad cow<br />

dise<strong>as</strong>e etc., that might drive the September price up to e.g. 90 cents per pound or<br />

down to e.g. 60 cents per pound to today’s expectation of 72 cents. Producers are<br />

rather interested in covering their production costs with certainty th<strong>an</strong> maximizing<br />

60 See [Keynes 1930].<br />

61 Following Section 2.3.1 there are different fin<strong>an</strong>cial vehicles the cattlem<strong>an</strong> c<strong>an</strong> use. He picks<br />

exch<strong>an</strong>ge traded futures contracts not OTC forward agreements because he w<strong>an</strong>ts to avoid<br />

counterparty default risk <strong>an</strong>d w<strong>an</strong>ts to deal with fair market not with bilateral bargained<br />

prices. Furthermore he does not chose a swap contract because he is not interested in a series<br />

of tr<strong>an</strong>sactions.<br />

45


3 Pricing of Commodity Futures<br />

their final gain. Lets <strong>as</strong>sume the cattlem<strong>an</strong>’s production costs to be 65 cents per<br />

pound, i.e. if the cattlem<strong>an</strong> h<strong>as</strong> to sell his production for less th<strong>an</strong> 65 cents per<br />

pound he will run out of business. To hedge future prices the cattlem<strong>an</strong> goes to<br />

the futures market <strong>an</strong>d sells today his production of tomorrow. To compensate<br />

investors for taking future price risks he needs to sell his production for a discount<br />

say 2 cents per pound <strong>an</strong>d the observable futures price becomes 70 cents per pound.<br />

The mech<strong>an</strong>ism is illustrated in Figure 3.1. 62<br />

Figure 3.1: The Risk Premium Model<br />

[Keynes 1930] argues that ”the spot price must exceed the forward price by the<br />

amount which the producer is ready to sacrifice in order to hedge himself, i.e. to<br />

avoid risk of price fluctuations during his production period. Thus, in normal conditions<br />

the spot price exceeds the forward price,” i.e. futures prices are set backwards<br />

to expected future spot prices. In the situation of normal backwardation nearby futures<br />

have higher values th<strong>an</strong> long term ones because the insur<strong>an</strong>ce premium payed<br />

for price fixity should naturally be higher for longer time dist<strong>an</strong>ces. The reverse situation<br />

is called cont<strong>an</strong>go. A famous example for the two phenomena is the NYMEX<br />

WTI crude oil market. During the p<strong>as</strong>t two decades the market w<strong>as</strong> approximately<br />

60% in backwardation. This trend reversed during the l<strong>as</strong>t two years. The WTI<br />

crude oil market h<strong>as</strong> spent 81% of the time in cont<strong>an</strong>go. 63 In this environment, oil<br />

consumers are willing to pay today a higher price for products delivered tomorrow.<br />

Usually this yields to <strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>e of inventories to guard against expected supply<br />

bottle necks, interruptions or even unavailability of the product. Figure 3.2 shows<br />

62 See also [Geer 2000].<br />

63 See [Merrill Lynch 2006].<br />

46


3.1 The Risk Premium Model<br />

the shape of the forward curve 64 of crude oil 65 <strong>an</strong>d copper 66 futures traded on the<br />

NYMEX per 31. J<strong>an</strong>uary 2006. The crude oil market is in cont<strong>an</strong>go <strong>an</strong>d the copper<br />

market is in backwardation.<br />

Figure 3.2: Backwardation <strong>an</strong>d Cont<strong>an</strong>go<br />

The theory of normal backwardation does not cover the practical phenomena cont<strong>an</strong>go.<br />

Therefore, [Cootner 1990] <strong>an</strong>d [Deaves Kinsky 1995] extended the theory<br />

<strong>an</strong>d formulated the hedging pressure hypothesis. They suggested that both ”backwardated”<br />

commodities, where today’s futures price is set below the expected future<br />

spot price, <strong>an</strong>d ”cont<strong>an</strong>goed” commodities, where today’s futures price is set above<br />

the expected future spot price, might have risk premiums. Backwardation occurs<br />

when hedgers are net short <strong>an</strong>d cont<strong>an</strong>go occurs when hedgers are net long in the<br />

respective futures market. Different statistical researches report evidence to proof<br />

this hypothesis. 67 Backwardated markets provide a hedge for producers, i.e. producers<br />

are willing to sell their products at <strong>an</strong> expected loss, <strong>an</strong>d cont<strong>an</strong>goed markets<br />

provide a hedge for consumers, i.e. consumers are willing to purch<strong>as</strong>e products at<br />

<strong>an</strong> expected loss. As a result, investors receive a risk premium for going long backwardated<br />

commodity futures <strong>an</strong>d for going short cont<strong>an</strong>goed commodity futures.<br />

Putting both theories into mathematical forms we end up with the Risk Premium<br />

Model:<br />

64 For <strong>an</strong> introduction to forward curves see [Zagst 2002].<br />

65 The values come from the NYMEX light sweet crude oil futures contract with a trading size of<br />

1.000 barrel <strong>as</strong> per 31. J<strong>an</strong>uary 2006.<br />

66 The values come from the LME copper futures contract with a trading size of 25 tones <strong>as</strong> per<br />

31. J<strong>an</strong>uary 2006.<br />

67 See e.g. [Anderson 2000], [Bessembinder 1992] or [DeRiin Nijm<strong>an</strong> Veld 2000].<br />

47


3 Pricing of Commodity Futures<br />

Theorem 3.1 Risk Premium Model<br />

Let P C (t) be the spot price of a commodity at time t ∈ [0, T ], let F t denote the<br />

σ-Algebra 68 <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.5 at time t <strong>an</strong>d let r p be the const<strong>an</strong>t <strong>as</strong>set specific<br />

risk premium. Moreover, define ˜Q <strong>as</strong> the equivalent martingale me<strong>as</strong>ure <strong>as</strong> of<br />

Definition C.32. Then the price of a commodity future F C (t, T ) at time t ∈ [0, T ] in<br />

the Risk Premium Model is given by:<br />

F C (t, T ) = e −rp(T −t) E ˜Q[P C (T )|F t ] (3.1)<br />

Proof: To distinguish between a traditional fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>set <strong>an</strong>d commodities <strong>as</strong><br />

<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set what embodies their consumption good function we are going to use the<br />

following notation:<br />

P A (t) denotes the spot price of a pure fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>set at time t ∈ [0, T ]<br />

P C (t) denotes the spot price of a commodity at time t ∈ [0, T ]<br />

F A (t, T ) denotes the futures price of a pure fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>set at time t ∈ [0, T ]<br />

F C (t, T ) denotes the futures price of a commodity at time t ∈ [0, T ]<br />

Furthermore let r f be the const<strong>an</strong>t risk free interest rate, r p be the const<strong>an</strong>t <strong>as</strong>set<br />

specific risk premium <strong>an</strong>d u the proportional cost of carry for <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set what c<strong>an</strong><br />

be seen <strong>as</strong> a negative dividend yield of a stock. The above <strong>as</strong>sumptions are made<br />

to simplify the model to give <strong>an</strong> e<strong>as</strong>y introduction of the concept of Risk Premium<br />

Models. Sure, they c<strong>an</strong> be modified what yields into the development of different<br />

customized applications, i.e. the risk free rate is in practice not const<strong>an</strong>t but<br />

stoch<strong>as</strong>tic <strong>an</strong>d the cost of carry may ch<strong>an</strong>ge over time <strong>as</strong> well.<br />

To exclude arbitrage opportunities in fin<strong>an</strong>cial markets, F A (t, T ) is the futures price<br />

for which the present value of the expected future payoff equals zero: 69<br />

0 = E ˜Q[e −(r f +u)(T −t) (P A (T ) − F A (t, T ))|F t ]<br />

F A (t, T ) = e (r f +u)(T −t) E ˜Q[e −(r f +u)(T −t) P A (T )|F t ]<br />

F A (t, T ) = E ˜Q[P A (T )|F t ] (3.2)<br />

68 The σ-Algebra F t embodies all available information until t. For a more detailed mathematical<br />

introduction see [Zagst 2002] or [Ito 2004].<br />

69 The idea behind this approach is that to avoid arbitrage opportunities, the prices of two fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

<strong>as</strong>sets producing the same payoff at maturity, have to be equal at each other time before<br />

maturity. For <strong>an</strong> illustrative introduction to risk neutral derivatives pricing see [Zagst 2002].<br />

48


3.1 The Risk Premium Model<br />

Risk Premium Models <strong>as</strong>sume that future prices of a consumption good have to<br />

include a risk premium. Therefore, the difference between the price of a commodity<br />

<strong>as</strong> a fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>set <strong>an</strong>d <strong>as</strong> a consumption good h<strong>as</strong> to be adjusted:<br />

P C (t) = e rp(T −t) P A (t) (3.3)<br />

Putting (3.3) into (3.2), the commodity futures price in the general Risk Premium<br />

Model is given <strong>as</strong> in Equation 3.1.<br />

✷<br />

The general Risk Premium Model represents the point of view that commodity<br />

futures prices equal the expected commodity spot price, discounted by a risk premium<br />

to compensate investors for holding the price risk of a commodity. B<strong>as</strong>ed on<br />

Equation (3.1) the return of a futures contract in the interval [s, t] with 0 ≤ s < t ≤<br />

T is given by:<br />

r FC (t,T )(s, t) ≡ ln<br />

( ) (3.1)<br />

( )<br />

FC (t, T ) {}}{<br />

E ˜Q[P C (T )|F t ]<br />

= r p (t − s) + ln<br />

F C (s, T ) } {{ } E ˜Q[P C (T )|F s ]<br />

risk premium } {{ }<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ge of price expectation<br />

(3.4)<br />

As we have seen above, according to the Risk Premium Model, the return <strong>an</strong> investor<br />

h<strong>as</strong> to look forward to is the sum of a risk premium <strong>an</strong>d the ch<strong>an</strong>ge in spot<br />

price expectations. To close the frame lets go back to the introductory example of<br />

the meatpacker. The ch<strong>an</strong>ge in spot price expectation is called the ”expectational<br />

vari<strong>an</strong>ce” <strong>an</strong>d illustrated in Figure 3.3. 70<br />

Recall, the meatpacker h<strong>as</strong> to cover his production costs. Therefore, he needs a fixed<br />

price <strong>an</strong>d is willing to enter into a futures contract to set the September price for his<br />

meat to 70 cents per pound although the expected future spot price is 72 cent. He<br />

pays a risk premium of 2 cents. Depending on possible events such <strong>as</strong> fear of mad cow<br />

dise<strong>as</strong>e, heavy barbecuing se<strong>as</strong>on etc., the spot price will run out somewhere between<br />

60 <strong>an</strong>d 90 cents what is either return boosting (positive expectational vari<strong>an</strong>ce) or<br />

destroying (negative expectational vari<strong>an</strong>ce).<br />

70 See [Geer 2000].<br />

49


3 Pricing of Commodity Futures<br />

Figure 3.3: The Concept of Expectational Vari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

3.2 The Convenience Yield Model<br />

The Convenience Yield Model is a no-arbitrage b<strong>as</strong>ed valuation concept. It values<br />

commodity futures with respect to the current commodity spot price <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong><br />

appropriate convenience yield. The fundamental behind this approach goes back<br />

to the theory of storage, first mentioned in [Kaldor 1939] <strong>an</strong>d further <strong>an</strong>alyzed in<br />

[Working 1948] <strong>an</strong>d [Working 1949]. The theory of storage aims to explain the differences<br />

between spot <strong>an</strong>d futures prices in dependency of the level of inventory <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the resulting benefits: inventories have a productive value since they allow to meet<br />

unexpected dem<strong>an</strong>d, avoid the cost of frequent revisions in the production schedule<br />

<strong>an</strong>d eliminate m<strong>an</strong>ufacturing disruption. In order to represent the adv<strong>an</strong>tages<br />

attached to the ownership of the physical good, [Kaldor 1939], [Working 1948] <strong>an</strong>d<br />

[Working 1949] defined the notion of the ”convenience yield”. It describes the benefit<br />

that ”accrues to the owner of the physical commodity but not to the holder of<br />

a forward contract.” In the same spirit, the dividend yield is paid to the owner of a<br />

stock but not to the owner of a derivative on the stock. The convenience yield is high<br />

when desired inventories are low <strong>an</strong>d vice versa. Consequently, the concept suggests<br />

on the one h<strong>an</strong>d that inventories might be low for commodities which are difficult to<br />

store. Therefore, they have a high convenience yield. On the other h<strong>an</strong>d inventories<br />

should be high for e<strong>as</strong>y to store commodities <strong>an</strong>d they should have low convenience<br />

yields. [Till 2000] did some related research. She reported that commodities with a<br />

difficult storage situation (storage is impossible, storage is prohibitively expensive,<br />

or producers decide that it is much cheaper to leave the commodity in the ground<br />

50


3.2 The Convenience Yield Model<br />

th<strong>an</strong> store above ground) produced a statistically signific<strong>an</strong>t positive return over<br />

the l<strong>as</strong>t 40 years. She mentioned amongst others livestock, copper <strong>an</strong>d crude oil.<br />

Implicating, the difficulty for a long term commodity investor is to determine future<br />

stocks of inventories.<br />

Putting the theory into mathematical forms we end up with the Convenience Yield<br />

Model:<br />

Theorem 3.2 Convenience-Yield Model<br />

Let P C (t) be the spot price of a commodity at time t ∈ [0, T ], u be the const<strong>an</strong>t<br />

cost of carry for <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set, c : R ↦→ R be the deterministic convenience yield <strong>an</strong>d let<br />

r f<br />

denote the const<strong>an</strong>t risk free interest rate, then the price of a commodity future<br />

F C (t, T ) at time t ∈ [0, T ] in the Convenience Yield Model is given by:<br />

F C (t, T ) = P C (t)e (r f +u−c(t))(T −t)<br />

(3.5)<br />

Proof:<br />

given by:<br />

With the notation of Theorem 3.1 the price of a commodity future is<br />

F C (t, T ) = e −rp(T −t) E ˜Q[P C (T )|F t ] (3.6)<br />

Furthermore, according to the most general form of a fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>set pricing model<br />

the current hypothetical ”<strong>as</strong>set price” of a physical commodity is the net present<br />

value of its expected future payoff P C (T ):<br />

P A (t) = e −(r f +r p+u)(T −t) E ˜Q[P C (T )|F t ] (3.7)<br />

Setting equal the expectations in Equation 3.6 <strong>an</strong>d 3.7 yields to:<br />

F C (t, T ) = e (r f +u)(T −t) P A (t) (3.8)<br />

Because of the additional consumption value of the physical commodity it is <strong>as</strong>sumed<br />

that the spot price of a commodity differs from the spot price of a pure fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

<strong>as</strong>set. Therefore, the commodity spot price needs to be adjusted:<br />

P C (t) = (1 + C(t))P A (t), with C(t) ≥ 0 (3.9)<br />

This equation states that the commodity spot price P C (t) exceeds the value of<br />

the spot price of a pure fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>set by the factor (1 + C(t)) that embodies<br />

the consumption good facility of the commodity. Because the convenience yield is<br />

defined <strong>as</strong> the benefit that accrues from holding the commodity it c<strong>an</strong> be seen <strong>as</strong><br />

a dividend which is payed to the holder of the commodity <strong>an</strong>d this yields to the<br />

51


3 Pricing of Commodity Futures<br />

common approximation for the convenience yield:<br />

(1 + C(t)) ∼ = e c(t)(T −t) (3.10)<br />

Putting this into Equation 3.9 yields to:<br />

P C (t) = e c(t)(T −t) P A (t) (3.11)<br />

Furthermore, putting this into Equation 3.8 yields to the result <strong>as</strong> in Equation (3.5).<br />

✷<br />

Remark 3.1 Sometimes the convenience yield is defined <strong>as</strong> net position of benefit<br />

from holding the commodity minus the storage costs. 71 The merged equation would<br />

become:<br />

F C (t, T ) = P C (t)e (r f −y(t))(T −t) , with y(t) = c(t) − u<br />

Remark 3.2 The convenience yield enters the futures price with a minus: the<br />

holder of the future does not benefit from the physical commodity over the time<br />

interval interval [t, T ]. Therefore, he is not be payed with the yield it provides.<br />

Remark 3.3 As mentioned introductory, the Convenience Yield Model is originally<br />

a no-arbitrage b<strong>as</strong>ed valuation concepts. Therefore, Theorem 3.2 is in literature<br />

mainly proofed with the following arbitrage argument: If the current futures<br />

price F C (t, T ) w<strong>as</strong> greater th<strong>an</strong> the right h<strong>an</strong>d side of Equation 3.5 namely<br />

P C (t)e (r f +u−c(t))(T −t) , one would sell the futures contract, buy the commodity through<br />

a lo<strong>an</strong>, pay the cost of carry, benefit from holding the physical commodity over the<br />

time interval (t, T ) <strong>an</strong>d realize at maturity T a c<strong>as</strong>h <strong>an</strong>d carry arbitrage. Consequently,<br />

if F C (t, T ) w<strong>as</strong> strictly smaller th<strong>an</strong> the right h<strong>an</strong>d side P C (t)e (r f +u−c(t))(T −t) ,<br />

a reverse c<strong>as</strong>h <strong>an</strong>d carry arbitrage would be possible. Therefore, equality must hold. 72<br />

In contr<strong>as</strong>t to Remark 3.3 the proof to Theorem 3.2 shows that the Risk Premium<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the Convenience Yield Model are directly connected to each other <strong>an</strong>d therefore,<br />

the two valuation approaches are mutually consistent: backwardation occurs when<br />

the convenience yield is high <strong>an</strong>d cont<strong>an</strong>go occurs when the convenience yield is low.<br />

This bridge w<strong>as</strong> first built in [Markert 2005] <strong>an</strong>d is unique in literature so far.<br />

From Equation 3.5 we c<strong>an</strong> take a closer look into the return structure of commodity<br />

71 See e.g. [Germ<strong>an</strong> 2005].<br />

72 See e.g. [Germ<strong>an</strong> 2005].<br />

52


3.3 Relationship of the Risk Premium <strong>an</strong>d Convenience Yield Model<br />

futures under the convenience yield model with 0 ≤ s < t ≤ T :<br />

( )<br />

FC (t, T )<br />

r FC (t,T )(s, t) ≡ ln<br />

F C (s, T )<br />

(3.5) ( )<br />

{}}{ PC (t)<br />

= ln + (r f + u − c(t))(T − t)<br />

P C (s)<br />

− (r f + u − c(s))(T − s)<br />

( )<br />

PC (t)<br />

= ln<br />

P C (s)<br />

} {{ }<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ge in spot price<br />

+ (c(t) − r f − u)(t − s)<br />

} {{ }<br />

cost of carry <strong>an</strong>d convenience yield<br />

+ (c(s) − c(t))(T − s)<br />

} {{ }<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ge in convenience yield<br />

(3.12)<br />

In the Convenience Yield Model the return provided by a futures contract is the<br />

sum of the ch<strong>an</strong>ge in commodity spot prices, the convenience yield minus the cost<br />

of carry <strong>an</strong>d the ch<strong>an</strong>ge of the convenience yield.<br />

The convenience yield h<strong>as</strong> neither to be const<strong>an</strong>t nor deterministic. In fact, <strong>an</strong><br />

<strong>as</strong>sumption of const<strong>an</strong>cy would be very unrealistic because the benefit of holding<br />

a commodity is reverse proportional to the stock of inventory <strong>an</strong>d fluctuates over<br />

time depending on the level of inventory. Therefore, researchers suggest stoch<strong>as</strong>tic<br />

models for the convenience yield which allow to explain the different shapes of the<br />

term structure, i.e. the different futures prices <strong>as</strong> a function of maturity. 73 We will<br />

address ourselves to this topic in Section 3.4.<br />

3.3 Relationship of the Risk Premium <strong>an</strong>d Convenience Yield<br />

Model<br />

The convenience yield conceptually links together desired inventories <strong>an</strong>d commodity<br />

futures prices. The benefit from holding the commodity is high when inventories are<br />

low. As a result, the convenience yield c<strong>an</strong> be thought of <strong>as</strong> a risk premium linked to<br />

inventory levels. Mathematically we c<strong>an</strong> see the connection by comparing Equation<br />

(3.12) <strong>an</strong>d Equation (3.4), i.e. by comparing the return structures according to the<br />

respective model.<br />

73 See [Gibson Schwartz 1990], [Schwartz 1997] or [C<strong>as</strong>s<strong>as</strong>us Collin-Dufresne 2005].<br />

53


3 Pricing of Commodity Futures<br />

Before we start we need to do the following pre calculation: With the thoughts of<br />

Equation (3.7) <strong>an</strong>d Equation (3.11) the spot price return with 0 ≤ s < t ≤ T c<strong>an</strong><br />

be calculated <strong>as</strong>:<br />

ln<br />

( )<br />

PC (t)<br />

P C (s)<br />

( )<br />

E ˜Q[P C (T )|F t ]<br />

= ln<br />

+ (c(t) − r<br />

E ˜Q[P f − r p − u)(T − t)<br />

C (T )|F ∫ ]<br />

− (c(s) − r f − r p − u)(T − s)<br />

( )<br />

E ˜Q[P C (T )|F t ]<br />

= ln<br />

+ (r<br />

E ˜Q[P f + r p + u − c(t))(t − s)<br />

C (T )|F ∫ ]<br />

+ (c(t) − c(s))(T − s) (3.13)<br />

Now, we c<strong>an</strong> derive the return according to the Risk Premium Model (R) out of the<br />

return according to the Convenience Yield Model (C):<br />

r FC (t,T ),C(s, t)<br />

(3.12) ( )<br />

{}}{ PC (t)<br />

= ln + (c(t) − r f − u)(t − s)<br />

P C (s)<br />

+ (c(s) − c(t))(T − s)<br />

( )<br />

(3.13)<br />

{}}{ E ˜Q[P C (T )|F t ]<br />

= ln<br />

+ (r<br />

E ˜Q[P f + r p + u − c(t))(t − s)<br />

C (T )|F s ]<br />

+ (c(t) − c(s))(T − s) + (c(t) − r f − u)(t − s)<br />

+ (c(s) − c(t))(T − s)<br />

( )<br />

E ˜Q[P C (T )|F t ]<br />

= r p (t − s) + ln<br />

E ˜Q[P C (T )|F s ]<br />

(3.4)<br />

{}}{<br />

= r FC (t,T ),R(s, t) (3.14)<br />

Therefore, depending on either view the futures price of a commodity is given by:<br />

F C (t, T ) = e −rp(T −t) E ˜Q[P C (T )|F t ]<br />

= P C (t)e (r f +u−c(t))(T −t)<br />

(3.15)<br />

Rearr<strong>an</strong>ging the right h<strong>an</strong>d side of Equation (3.15) shows the influencing factors of<br />

the expected ch<strong>an</strong>ge in commodity spot prices:<br />

ln ( E ˜Q[P C (T )|F t ] ) ( )<br />

E ˜Q[P C (T )|F t ]<br />

− ln (P C (t)) = ln<br />

P C (t)<br />

= (r f + r p + u − c(t))(T − t) (3.16)<br />

For fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>sets, with c(t) = 0 <strong>an</strong>d u equaling a negative dividend yield, above<br />

54


3.4 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Models<br />

Equation (3.16) states that in <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set pricing equilibrium the spot price is expected<br />

to grow by the risk free rate plus the risk premium minus the dividend yield. In<br />

stoch<strong>as</strong>tic stock price models this is captured in the drift rate of the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic<br />

process modeling the stock price. Thus, the gr<strong>as</strong>s roots needed to underst<strong>an</strong>d the<br />

origins of the different stoch<strong>as</strong>tic models for commodity prices, e.g. introduced<br />

in [Gibson Schwartz 1990], [Schwartz 1997] or [C<strong>as</strong>s<strong>as</strong>us Collin-Dufresne 2005] are<br />

disclosed <strong>an</strong>d the following section shall give a brief introduction of the different<br />

approaches. 74<br />

3.4 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Models<br />

The term structure gives the relationship between the futures prices <strong>an</strong>d the respective<br />

time to maturity. It provides useful information for hedging or investment<br />

decisions because it synthesizes the information available in the market <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

operators’ expectations concerning the future. The information is very useful for<br />

m<strong>an</strong>agement purposes: it c<strong>an</strong> be used to hedge exposure on the physical market<br />

<strong>an</strong>d to adjust the stock level or the production rate. It c<strong>an</strong> also be used to undertake<br />

arbitrage tr<strong>an</strong>sactions, to evaluate derivatives instruments b<strong>as</strong>ed on futures<br />

contracts, <strong>an</strong>d so on. Therefore, stoch<strong>as</strong>tic term structure models aim to reproduce<br />

the futures prices observed in the market <strong>as</strong> accurately <strong>as</strong> possible aiming e.g. to<br />

discover futures prices for horizons exceeding exch<strong>an</strong>ge traded maturities, to forec<strong>as</strong>t<br />

futures price developments under different economic scenarios, to price structured<br />

products b<strong>as</strong>ed on futures contracts with minimized errors or to see the interactions<br />

of futures prices with other <strong>as</strong>set’s price movements.<br />

Over time, different models were introduced r<strong>an</strong>ging from the simplest one factor<br />

models to more sophisticated versions of three factor models. Depending on the<br />

amount of factors, the following factors are modeled stoch<strong>as</strong>tically: the spot price,<br />

the convenience yield <strong>an</strong>d the interest rate. Starting in Section 3.4.1 we will introduce<br />

two examples of one factor models. The first, called Browni<strong>an</strong> Motion Model,<br />

will generate the spot price with a stoch<strong>as</strong>tic dynamic coming from a Browni<strong>an</strong><br />

Motion <strong>an</strong>d a deterministic convenience yield.<br />

The second, called Me<strong>an</strong> Reversion<br />

Model, will model the spot price over a me<strong>an</strong> reverting dynamic structure.<br />

In Section 3.4.2 we will introduce the two most accepted two factor models: the<br />

Convenience Yield <strong>an</strong>d the Long - Short Term Model. Although, the two models<br />

were developed b<strong>as</strong>ed on different fundamental ide<strong>as</strong>, the two models are equivalent.<br />

74 We will further denote the futures price of a commodity with F (t, T ) = F C (t, T ) <strong>an</strong>d its spot<br />

price with P (t) = P C (t) at t ∈ [0, T ].<br />

55


3 Pricing of Commodity Futures<br />

Closing this section we will give a brief example of a three factor model. It is similar<br />

to the Convenience Yield Model of Section 3.4.2, but extended with a stoch<strong>as</strong>tic<br />

interest rate component.<br />

To evaluate futures prices b<strong>as</strong>ed on the three input factors commodity spot price,<br />

convenience yield <strong>an</strong>d interest rate, given either deterministic or stoch<strong>as</strong>tic, the<br />

models borrow from the contingent claim <strong>an</strong>alysis developed for stock <strong>an</strong>d interest<br />

rate models. 75 Therefore, the different models of commodity futures pricing share<br />

the following general <strong>as</strong>sumptions: the market for <strong>as</strong>sets is free of frictions, taxes or<br />

tr<strong>an</strong>saction costs, trading takes place continuously <strong>an</strong>d lending <strong>an</strong>d borrowing rates<br />

are equal <strong>an</strong>d there are no short sale constrains.<br />

3.4.1 One Factor Models<br />

One factor models are b<strong>as</strong>ed on the concept that futures prices are determined <strong>as</strong><br />

the expectation of the future spot price, conditionally to the available information<br />

at time t. Therefore, the spot price is the main determin<strong>an</strong>t of futures prices.<br />

Thus, following [Lautier 2005], most one factor models rely on the spot price. Two<br />

general approaches are chosen: either to model the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic dynamic of the spot<br />

price with a Browni<strong>an</strong> Motion or with a Me<strong>an</strong> Reversion Process. The Browni<strong>an</strong><br />

Motion Model is more excepted in practice th<strong>an</strong> the Me<strong>an</strong> Reversion Model because<br />

it allows for a deterministic convenience yield <strong>an</strong>d therefore, covers the consumption<br />

good characteristic of commodities. On the other h<strong>an</strong>d, the Browni<strong>an</strong> Motion Model<br />

does not cover observed me<strong>an</strong> reversion pattern in commodity futures prices. We<br />

will introduce both approaches to give a general overview of common market models,<br />

starting in Definition 3.1 with the Browni<strong>an</strong> Motion Model.<br />

Definition 3.1 Browni<strong>an</strong> Motion Model<br />

Let P (t) be the spot price of a commodity at time t ∈ [0, T ], µ ∈ R the drift of the<br />

spot price, σ P > 0 the spot price volatility <strong>an</strong>d W P (t) a st<strong>an</strong>dard Browni<strong>an</strong> Motion<br />

<strong>as</strong> defined in Definition C.28. Then the dynamic of the spot price in the Geometric<br />

Browni<strong>an</strong> Motion Model is<br />

dP (t) = µP (t)dt + σ P P (t)dW P (t), t ∈ [0, T ]. (3.17)<br />

Equation (3.17) stats that the commodity spot price is driven by a stoch<strong>as</strong>tic that<br />

c<strong>an</strong> be modeled with a simple Browni<strong>an</strong> Motion. B<strong>as</strong>ed on this stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process,<br />

75 An illustrative introduction c<strong>an</strong> be found in [Zagst 2002].<br />

56


3.4 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Models<br />

we will further derive the futures price represented by F (P, t) at time t for delivery<br />

of one unit of the commodity at time T . Furthermore, denote:<br />

∂F (P,t)<br />

∂t<br />

= F t (P, t)<br />

∂F (P,t)<br />

∂P<br />

= F P (P, t)<br />

∂ 2 F (P,t)<br />

∂ 2 P<br />

= F P P (P, t) 2 .<br />

Using Itô’s lemma <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.1, the inst<strong>an</strong>t<strong>an</strong>eous ch<strong>an</strong>ge in the futures price<br />

is given <strong>as</strong>:<br />

dF (P, t) =<br />

(3.17)<br />

{}}{<br />

=<br />

=<br />

[<br />

F t (P, t) + µP (t)F P (P, t) + 1 ]<br />

2 σ2 P P (t) 2 F P P (P, t) dt<br />

+ σ P P (t)F P (P, t)dW P (t)<br />

[<br />

F t (P, t) + 1 ]<br />

2 σ2 P P (t) 2 F P P (P, t) dt<br />

⎡<br />

⎢<br />

⎥<br />

+ F P (P, t) ⎣µP (t)dt + σ P P (t)dW P (t) ⎦<br />

} {{ }<br />

dP (t)<br />

[<br />

F t (P, t) + 1 ]<br />

2 σ2 P P (t) 2 F P P (P, t) dt + F P (P, t)dP (t) (3.18)<br />

⎤<br />

The difference between commodities <strong>as</strong> simple fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>set <strong>an</strong>d consumption good<br />

is captured in the net convenience yield 76 <strong>as</strong>sumed to be a proportional to the<br />

spot price: c(P, t) = CP (t), with C ∈ R. Following [Brenn<strong>an</strong> Schwartz 1985] the<br />

convenience yield is the flow of services that accrues to <strong>an</strong> owner of the physical<br />

commodity. He is able to choose where the commodity will be stored <strong>an</strong>d when<br />

to liquidate the inventory. Recognizing the costs for tr<strong>an</strong>sportation, storage <strong>an</strong>d<br />

insur<strong>an</strong>ce, the convenience yield ”may be thought of <strong>as</strong> the value of being able to<br />

profit from temporary local shortages of the commodity through ownership of the<br />

physical commodity. The profit may arise either from local price variations or from<br />

the ability to maintain a production process <strong>as</strong> a result of ownership of <strong>an</strong> inventory<br />

of raw material.” Therefore, the fin<strong>an</strong>cial spot price process dP (t) h<strong>as</strong> to be amended<br />

with the convenience yield process CP (t)dt yielding to the actual commodity spot<br />

76 Compare Remark 3.1 of Section 3.2.<br />

57


3 Pricing of Commodity Futures<br />

price process: 77<br />

dP (t) + CP (t)dt = µP (t)dt + σ P P (t)dW P (t), t ∈ [0, T ]<br />

⇒ dP (t) = (µ − C)P (t)dt + σ P P (t)dW P (t) (3.19)<br />

Following the no arbitrage pricing methodology, the futures contract delivering one<br />

unit of the underlying in T h<strong>as</strong> the same value <strong>as</strong> the commodity in T . To avoid<br />

arbitrage, the two <strong>as</strong>sets must have the same value before T , <strong>as</strong> well. Therefore, we<br />

c<strong>an</strong> construct the following portfolio, called risk free hedge portfolio:<br />

with:<br />

V (t) = P (t) + c(P, t) − δF (P, t)<br />

dV (t) = dP (t) + CP (t)dt − δdF (P, t)<br />

(3.18)<br />

[<br />

{}}{<br />

= dP (t) + CP (t)dt − δ( F t (P, t) + 1 ]<br />

2 σ2 P P (t) 2 F P P (P, t) dt<br />

+ F P (P, t)dP (t))<br />

= [CP (t) − δ(F t (P, t) + 1 2 σ2 P P (t) 2 F P P (P, t))]dt<br />

δ= 1<br />

F P (P,t)<br />

{}}{<br />

=<br />

risk free<br />

{}}{<br />

≡<br />

+ (dP (t) − δF P (P, t)dP (t))<br />

} {{ }<br />

risk free⇔=0⇔δ= 1<br />

F P (P,t)<br />

[<br />

1<br />

CP (t)F P (P, t) − F t (P, t) − 1 ]<br />

F P (P, t)<br />

2 σ2 P P (t) 2 F P P (P, t) dt<br />

r f P (t)dt<br />

Thus, the futures price in the Browni<strong>an</strong> Motion Model is given <strong>as</strong> the solution of<br />

the following partial differential equation with the boundary condition F (P (t), T ) =<br />

P (T ):<br />

F t (P, t) + 1 2 σ2 P P (t) 2 F P P (P, t) + F P (P, t)P (t)(r f − C) = 0 (3.20)<br />

77 Compare Equation (3.9).<br />

58


Definition C.32: 78 F (P, t) = E ˜Q[P (T )|F t ], t ∈ [0, T ] (3.22)<br />

3.4 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Models<br />

Theorem 3.3 Futures Price in the Browni<strong>an</strong> Motion Model<br />

Let the notations be <strong>as</strong> in Definition 3.1, c(P, t) = CP (t) with C ∈ R be the deterministic<br />

convenience yield <strong>an</strong>d r f be the const<strong>an</strong>t risk free interest rate. Then the<br />

futures price F (P, t) is a function of the spot price <strong>an</strong>d the time to maturity:<br />

F (P, t) = P (t)e (r f −C)(T −t) . (3.21)<br />

Proof: It h<strong>as</strong> been shown in [Zagst 2002], that the futures price F (t) of <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set<br />

is the conditional expectation <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.24, whereby conditional is regarding<br />

the available information of today embodied in σ-Algebra F t <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.5,<br />

of its future spot price P (T ) under the equivalent martingale me<strong>as</strong>ure ˜Q <strong>as</strong> of<br />

Using the Feynm<strong>an</strong>-Kac representation of Theorem C.5, there is <strong>an</strong> indirect way to<br />

get (3.22). Someone c<strong>an</strong> solve the Cauchy-Problem <strong>as</strong> given in Definition C.36 to<br />

get the solution of the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic differential equation underlying the futures price.<br />

The Feynm<strong>an</strong>-Kac representation then stats that if there exists a solution that it is<br />

equal to conditional expectation of (3.22). 79<br />

To get F (P, t) = v(P, t) <strong>as</strong> requested<br />

in Equation (C.25), we have to define: x := P , r(P, t) ≡ 0 <strong>an</strong>d D(P ) := P (T ).<br />

Therewith, we have to show that F solves the Cauchy-Problem <strong>as</strong> defined in C.36.<br />

For it, we first have to tr<strong>an</strong>sfer the spot price P in the world of the equivalent martingale<br />

me<strong>as</strong>ure ˜Q which exists because of the Girs<strong>an</strong>ov-Theorem <strong>as</strong> of Theorem C.3.<br />

Denote with d ˜W the increments of the Browni<strong>an</strong> motion <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.28 under<br />

˜Q. Using the Girs<strong>an</strong>ov-Theorem <strong>as</strong> of Theorem C.3, we have:<br />

d ˜W (t) = λ(t)dt + dW (t), t ∈ [0, T ] (3.23)<br />

where λ : R ↦→ R is called the market price of risk. It results<br />

dP (t) = [µ − σ P λ(t)]P (t)dt + σ P P (t)d ˜W P (t), t ∈ [0, T ] (3.24)<br />

where it h<strong>as</strong> to be µ − σ P λ(t) = r f because the discounted spot price process h<strong>as</strong> to<br />

be a martingale <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.29. It is<br />

dP (t) = r f P (t)dt + σ P P (t)d ˜W P (t), t ∈ [0, T ]. (3.25)<br />

78 Also compare Equation (3.2).<br />

79 Attention: The opposite direction is not always true. See [Zagst 2002].<br />

59


3 Pricing of Commodity Futures<br />

Again, we have to amend the fin<strong>an</strong>cial spot price of commodities with the convenience<br />

yield process <strong>as</strong> in Equation (3.19). It follows<br />

dP (t) = (r f − C)P (t)dt + σ P P (t)d ˜W P (t), t ∈ [0, T ] (3.26)<br />

Then, the adapted Cauchy-Problem <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.36 is given <strong>as</strong>:<br />

F t (P, t) + 1 2 σ2 P P (t) 2 F P P (P, t) + F P (P, t)P (t)(r f − C) = 0, t ∈ [0, T ] (3.27)<br />

with the terminal boundary condition F (P, T ) = P (T ). Recall, this is equal to<br />

Equation (3.20) <strong>an</strong>d therefore shows, that solving the Cauchy Problem is in line<br />

with solving the differential equation developed over the no arbitrage approach.<br />

Under the <strong>as</strong>sumption of Equation (3.21), F (P, t) = P (t)e (r f −C)(T −t) , with t ∈ [0, T ],<br />

we get:<br />

F P (P, t) = e (r f −C)(T −t) ,<br />

F P,P (P, t) = 0,<br />

F t (P, t) = −(r f − C)F (P, t), t ∈ [0, T ].<br />

Putting this into the Cauchy-Problem, Equation (3.27), it follows<br />

0 + (r f − C)F (P, t) − (r f − C)F (P, t) = 0, ∀t ∈ [0, T ]<br />

which shows, that the futures price is indeed F (P, t) = P (t)e (r f −C)(T −t) .<br />

✷<br />

Although, the Browni<strong>an</strong> Motion Model is probably the most simple <strong>an</strong>d therewith<br />

the most known one, it h<strong>as</strong> the drawback of not covering me<strong>an</strong> reversion occurring in<br />

commodity spot prices caused by the consumption good characteristic of commodities<br />

reflecting producers <strong>an</strong>d consumers actions in the physical market. 80 When the<br />

spot price is low, industrials expect prices to rise <strong>an</strong>d fill their inventories. Producers<br />

react with a reduction of output providing only low benefits. The incre<strong>as</strong>ed dem<strong>an</strong>d<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the simult<strong>an</strong>eous reduction of supply have a rising influence on the spot price.<br />

Conversely, when the spot price is higher th<strong>an</strong> its long run average, industrials will<br />

serve their dem<strong>an</strong>d with inventories that were build up at low commodity price times<br />

<strong>an</strong>d producers incre<strong>as</strong>e their production rate expecting higher margins for the same<br />

80 See the latest work [Markert 2005].<br />

60


3.4 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Models<br />

output. Both movements will push the spot price to lower levels. [Schwartz 1997]<br />

published a one factor model that directly incorporates the me<strong>an</strong> reversion effect<br />

into the spot price.<br />

Definition 3.2 Me<strong>an</strong> Reversion Model<br />

Let P (t) be the spot price of a commodity at time t ∈ [0, T ], µ ∈ R the longrun<br />

me<strong>an</strong>, κ > 0 the speed of adjustment of the spot price, σ P > 0 the spot price<br />

volatility <strong>an</strong>d W P (t) a st<strong>an</strong>dard Browni<strong>an</strong> motion <strong>as</strong> defined in Definition C.28.<br />

Then the dynamic of the spot price in the Me<strong>an</strong>-Reverting Model is<br />

dP (t) = P (t)κ[µ − ln P (t)]dt + σ P P (t)dW P (t), t ∈ [0, T ]. (3.28)<br />

The model covers two characteristics of me<strong>an</strong> reversion: the spot price h<strong>as</strong> the<br />

prosperity to return to its long-term me<strong>an</strong>, but simult<strong>an</strong>eously, r<strong>an</strong>dom shocks c<strong>an</strong><br />

move it away in the short-run allowing for sudden price peaks.<br />

B<strong>as</strong>ed on the spot price movements we c<strong>an</strong> calculate the futures price in the Me<strong>an</strong><br />

Reversion Model:<br />

Theorem 3.4 Futures Price in the Me<strong>an</strong> Reversion Model<br />

Let the notations be <strong>as</strong> in Definition 3.2, λ : R ↦→ R be the market price of risk<br />

introduced in the Girs<strong>an</strong>ov-Theorem <strong>as</strong> of Theorem C.3 <strong>an</strong>d r f be the const<strong>an</strong>t risk<br />

free interest rate. Then the futures price F (P, t) is a function of the spot price <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the time to maturity <strong>an</strong>d is expressed by<br />

with t ∈ [0, T ].<br />

Proof:<br />

F (P, t) = exp[e −κ(T −t) ln P (t) + (1 − e −κ(T −t) )(µ − σ 2 P /2κ − λ)<br />

+ σ2 P<br />

4κ (1 − e−2κ(T −t) )], (3.29)<br />

As shown in Proof 3.4.1, the futures price F must solve the Cauchy-<br />

Problem <strong>as</strong> defined in Definition C.36 with x := P , r(P, t) ≡ 0 <strong>an</strong>d D(P ) := P (T )<br />

for all P (T ) ∈ R <strong>an</strong>d t ∈ [0, T ]. Following the methodology of Proof 3.4.1 we have<br />

to tr<strong>an</strong>sfer the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process for the factors into the world of the equivalent<br />

martingale me<strong>as</strong>ure ˜Q. Using the Girs<strong>an</strong>ov-Theorem <strong>as</strong> of Theorem C.3, we have:<br />

dP (t) = P (t)κ[µ − ln P (t) − λ]dt + σ P P (t)d ˜W P (t), t ∈ [0, T ].<br />

d ˜W P (t) is the increment of a Browni<strong>an</strong> motions under the equivalent martingale<br />

me<strong>as</strong>ure. B<strong>as</strong>ed on this equations the adapted Cauchy-Problem <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.36<br />

61


3 Pricing of Commodity Futures<br />

is given <strong>as</strong>:<br />

1<br />

2 σ2 P P (t) 2 F P,P (P, t) + P (t)κ[µ − ln P (t) − λ]F P (P, t) + F t (P, t) = 0 (3.30)<br />

with t ∈ [0, T ] <strong>an</strong>d the terminal boundary condition F (P, T ) = P (T ).<br />

Under the <strong>as</strong>sumption of Equation (3.34), that<br />

[<br />

]<br />

F (P, t) = exp e −κ(T −t) ln P (t) + (1 − e −κ(T −t) )(µ − σP 2 /2κ − λ) + σ2 P<br />

4κ (1 − e−2κ(T −t) )<br />

with t ∈ [0, T ], we c<strong>an</strong> calculate the respective derivatives:<br />

F P (P, t) = e −κ(T −t) F (P,t)<br />

P (t) ,<br />

F P,P (P, t) = e −2κ(T −t) F (P,t)<br />

− e −κ(T −t) F (P,t)<br />

,<br />

P (t) 2<br />

P (t) 2 ]<br />

F t (P, t) =<br />

[κe −κ(T −t) (ln P (t) + λ − µ + σP 2 /2κ) − σ2 P<br />

2<br />

e −2κ(T −t) F (P, t), t ∈ [0, T ].<br />

Putting this into the Cauchy-Problem of Equation (3.30) it follows:<br />

1<br />

2 σ2 P F (P, t) ( e −2κ(T −t) − e −κ(T −t)) + κe −κ(T −t) [µ − ln P (t) − λ]F (P, t)<br />

[<br />

]<br />

+ κe −κ(T −t) (ln P (t) + λ − µ + σP 2 /2κ) − σ2 P<br />

2 e−2κ(T −t) F (P, t)<br />

= κe −κ(T −t) [µ − ln P (t) − λ]F (P, t) + κe −κ(T −t) [ln P (t) + λ − µ] F (P, t)<br />

= 0, t ∈ [0, T ]<br />

which shows that F (P, t) solves the Cauchy-Problem <strong>as</strong> of Equation (3.30).<br />

Finally, we have to prove that our <strong>as</strong>sumption solves the terminal boundary condition<br />

F (P, T ) = P (T ). Under our <strong>as</strong>sumption it holds<br />

F (P, T ) = exp<br />

This proves our <strong>as</strong>sumption.<br />

[<br />

−κ(T −T )<br />

−κ(T −T )<br />

e} {{ } ln P (T ) + (1<br />

}<br />

− e<br />

{{ }<br />

)(µ − σP 2 /2κ − λ)<br />

=1<br />

=0<br />

]<br />

+ σ2 P<br />

−T )<br />

(1 − e−2κ(T<br />

4κ } {{ }<br />

)<br />

=0<br />

= P (T ).<br />

✷<br />

62


3.4 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Models<br />

The model h<strong>as</strong> the major drawback that it treats positive <strong>an</strong>d negative me<strong>an</strong> reversion<br />

in the same way. Following [Lautier 2005] cont<strong>an</strong>go is limited to the storage<br />

costs until a certain maturity resulting in <strong>an</strong> upper boundary for price spreads between<br />

two maturity following futures contracts, while backwardation is not. To<br />

cover this phenomena, more complex models are needed.<br />

3.4.2 Two Factor Models<br />

Two factor models determine the uncertainty in the commodity spot price over two<br />

r<strong>an</strong>dom processes. Two approaches are excepted in literature: the convenience yield<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the long-short term approach. Although the models look different on the first<br />

view, they are equivalent what we will show later. Starting this section we introduce<br />

the Convenience Yield Model allowing for a stoch<strong>as</strong>tic spot price implicitly driven<br />

by a stoch<strong>as</strong>tic convenience yield. Recall, convenience yield determines why <strong>an</strong>d<br />

how commodity spot prices deviate from cl<strong>as</strong>sical <strong>as</strong>set prices. The following stoch<strong>as</strong>tic<br />

model specifies the spot price implicitly driven by the convenience yield that<br />

is modeled exogenously <strong>as</strong> a me<strong>an</strong> revering process <strong>an</strong>d determine the futures price<br />

<strong>as</strong> the risk neutral expectation of future spot prices. The model w<strong>as</strong> first introduced<br />

in [Schwartz 1997] <strong>an</strong>d is given in Definition 3.3.<br />

Definition 3.3 Convenience Yield Model<br />

Let P (t) be the spot price of a commodity at time t ∈ [0, T ], c(t) the convenience yield<br />

at time t, µ ∈ R the drift of the spot price, α ∈ R is the long-run level to which the<br />

convenience yield reverts, κ > 0 is the speed of adjustment of the convenience yield,<br />

σ P > 0 the spot price volatility, σ c > 0 the convenience yield volatility <strong>an</strong>d dW P (t)<br />

<strong>an</strong>d dW c (t) the increments of two Browni<strong>an</strong> Motions <strong>as</strong> defined in Definition C.28<br />

with a correlation<br />

dW P (t)dW c (t) = ρdt, t ∈ [0, T ], ρ ∈ [−1, 1]. (3.31)<br />

The spot price <strong>an</strong>d the inst<strong>an</strong>t<strong>an</strong>eous convenience yield process are <strong>as</strong>sumed to have<br />

the following form:<br />

dP (t) = P (t)[µ − c(t)]dt + σ P P (t)dW P (t), (3.32)<br />

dc(t) = κ[α − c(t)]dt + σ c dW c (t), t ∈ [0, T ] (3.33)<br />

The spot price P (t) of Equation (3.32) follows a geometric Browni<strong>an</strong> Motion <strong>as</strong><br />

of Definition C.28 with a stoch<strong>as</strong>tic convenience yield defined in Equation (3.33).<br />

63


3 Pricing of Commodity Futures<br />

The stoch<strong>as</strong>tic convenience yield c(t) <strong>as</strong> of Equation (3.33) is <strong>as</strong>sumed to be me<strong>an</strong><br />

reverting <strong>an</strong>d follows a Me<strong>an</strong> Reversion process. The inclusion of this process into<br />

Equation (3.32) introduces <strong>an</strong> implicit me<strong>an</strong> reversion effect on the commodity spot<br />

price process, when the respective Browni<strong>an</strong> Motions are positively correlated: An<br />

incre<strong>as</strong>e in P (t) from a positive dW P (t) is typically <strong>as</strong>sociated with a positive dW c (t)<br />

<strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>e of c(t) entering negative the drift rate of P (t) <strong>an</strong>d decre<strong>as</strong>ing the<br />

spot price. 81 B<strong>as</strong>ed on the spot price movements we c<strong>an</strong> calculate the futures price<br />

in the Convenience Yield Model:<br />

Theorem 3.5 Futures Price in the Convenience Yield Model<br />

Let the notations be <strong>as</strong> in Definition (3.3), λ : R ↦→ R be the market price of risk<br />

introduced in the Girs<strong>an</strong>ov-Theorem <strong>as</strong> of Theorem C.3 <strong>an</strong>d r f be the const<strong>an</strong>t risk<br />

free interest rate. Then the futures price F (P, c, t) is a function of the spot price,<br />

the convenience yield <strong>an</strong>d the time to maturity <strong>an</strong>d is expressed by<br />

[ ( )<br />

1 − e<br />

−κ(T −t)<br />

F (P, c, t) = P (t) exp −c(t)<br />

κ<br />

]<br />

+ A(T, t) , t ∈ [0, T ] (3.34)<br />

with<br />

A(T, t) =<br />

(<br />

r f − α + λ κ + 1 σc<br />

2<br />

2<br />

+<br />

([<br />

α − λ ]<br />

κ + σ P σ c ρ − σ2 c<br />

κ<br />

κ<br />

κ − σ )<br />

P σ c ρ<br />

(T − t) + 1 2 κ<br />

4 σ2 c<br />

) 1 − e<br />

−κ(T −t)<br />

−2κ(T −t)<br />

1 − e<br />

κ 3<br />

κ 2 (3.35)<br />

Proof: As shown in Proof 3.4.1, the futures price F must solve the Cauchy-<br />

Problem <strong>as</strong> defined in Definition C.36 with x := P , r(P, t) ≡ 0 <strong>an</strong>d D(P ) := P (T )<br />

for all P (T ) ∈ R <strong>an</strong>d t ∈ [0, T ]. Following the methodology of Proof 3.4.1, we have<br />

to tr<strong>an</strong>sfer the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process for the factors into the world of the equivalent<br />

martingale me<strong>as</strong>ure ˜Q <strong>as</strong> defined in Definition C.32. Using the Girs<strong>an</strong>ov-Theorem<br />

<strong>as</strong> of Theorem C.3, we have:<br />

dP (t) = P (t)[r f − c(t)]dt + σ P P (t)d ˜W P (t),<br />

dc(t) = (κ[α − c(t)] − λ)dt + σ c d ˜W c (t),<br />

d ˜W P (t)d ˜W c (t) = ρdt, t ∈ [0, T ]<br />

d ˜W P (t) <strong>an</strong>d d ˜W c (t) are the increments of two Browni<strong>an</strong> motions under the equivalent<br />

martingale me<strong>as</strong>ure. B<strong>as</strong>ed on these equations we c<strong>an</strong> formulated the specific<br />

81 See [Markert 2005] for empirical evidence.<br />

64


3.4 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Models<br />

Cauchy-Problem:<br />

0 = 1 2 σ2 P P (t) 2 F P,P (P, c, t) + ρσ P σ c P (t)F P,c (P, c, t)<br />

+ 1 2 σ2 c F c,c (P, c, t) + [r f − c(t)]P (t)F P (P, c, t)<br />

+ (κ[α − c(t)] − λ)F c (P, c, t) + F t (P, c, t), t ∈ [0, T ] (3.36)<br />

with the terminal boundary condition F (P, c, T ) = P (T ).<br />

Under the <strong>as</strong>sumption of Equation (3.34) that<br />

[ ( )<br />

1 − e<br />

−κ(T −t)<br />

F (P, c, t) = P (t) exp −c(t)<br />

κ<br />

]<br />

+ A(T, t) , t ∈ [0, T ]<br />

with<br />

A(T, t) =<br />

(<br />

r f − α + λ κ + 1 σc<br />

2<br />

2<br />

+<br />

([<br />

α − λ ]<br />

κ + σ P σ c ρ − σ2 c<br />

κ<br />

κ<br />

κ − σ )<br />

P σ c ρ<br />

(T − t) + 1 2 κ<br />

4 σ2 c<br />

) 1 − e<br />

−κ(T −t)<br />

−2κ(T −t)<br />

1 − e<br />

κ 3<br />

κ 2 , t ∈ [0, T ]<br />

we c<strong>an</strong> calculate the respective derivatives:<br />

F P (P, c, t) = F (P,c,t)<br />

P (t)<br />

,<br />

F P,P (P, c, t) = 0,<br />

F c (P, c, t) = −<br />

F c,c (P, c, t) =<br />

(<br />

1−e<br />

(<br />

F P,c (P, c, t) = −<br />

−κ(T −t)<br />

κ<br />

(<br />

1−e−κ(T −t)<br />

κ<br />

1−e−κ(T −t)<br />

P (t)κ<br />

)<br />

F (P, c, t),<br />

) 2<br />

F (P, c, t),<br />

)<br />

F (P, c, t),<br />

<strong>an</strong>d finally,<br />

F t (P, c, t) =<br />

[<br />

(<br />

c(t)e −κ(T −t) − r f − α + λ κ + 1 σc<br />

2<br />

2 κ − σ )<br />

P σ c ρ<br />

2 κ<br />

− 1 ([<br />

α − λ ]<br />

κ + σ P σ c ρ − σ2 c<br />

κ κ<br />

κ<br />

)<br />

e −κ(T −t) ]<br />

F (P, c, t)<br />

− σ2 c −t)<br />

e−2κ(T<br />

2κ2 with t ∈ [0, T ].<br />

65


3 Pricing of Commodity Futures<br />

Putting this into the Cauchy-Problem Equation (3.36) it follows<br />

0 + 1 ( ) 1 − e<br />

−κ(T −t) 2<br />

2 σ2 c<br />

F (P, c, t) + [r f − c(t)]F (P, c, t)<br />

κ<br />

( )<br />

1 − e<br />

−κ(T −t)<br />

− (κ[α − c(t)] − λ + ρσ P σ c )<br />

F (P, c, t)<br />

κ<br />

[<br />

(<br />

+ c(t)e −κ(T −t) − r f − α + λ κ + 1 σc<br />

2<br />

2 κ − σ )<br />

P σ c ρ<br />

− σ2 c −t)<br />

2 e−2κ(T<br />

κ 2κ2 − 1 ([<br />

α − λ ]<br />

) ]<br />

κ + σ P σ c ρ − σ2 c<br />

e −κ(T −t) F (P, c, t)<br />

κ κ<br />

κ<br />

= [r f − c(t)]F (P, c, t) − 1 κ (κ[α − c(t)] − λ + ρσ P σ c ) ( 1 − e −κ(T −t)) F (P, c, t)<br />

[<br />

(<br />

+ c(t)e −κ(T −t) − r f − α + λ κ − σ )<br />

P σ c ρ<br />

κ<br />

− 1 ([<br />

α − λ ] ) ]<br />

κ + σ P σ c ρ e −κ(T −t) F (P, c, t)<br />

κ κ<br />

= 1 κ (κ[α − c(t)] − λ + ρσ P σ c )e −κ(T −t) F (P, c, t)<br />

[<br />

+ c(t)e −κ(T −t) − 1 ([<br />

α − λ ] ) ]<br />

κ + σ P σ c ρ e −κ(T −t) F (P, c, t)<br />

κ κ<br />

= 1 κ (κ[α − c(t)] − λ + ρσ P σ c )e −κ(T −t) F (P, c, t)<br />

− 1 κ (κ[α − c(t)] − λ + ρσ P σ c )e −κ(T −t) F (P, c, t)<br />

= 0, t ∈ [0, T ]<br />

which shows that indeed F (P, c, t) <strong>as</strong> of Equation (3.34) solves the Cauchy-Problem<br />

Equation (3.36). Still we have to prove that our <strong>as</strong>sumption solves the terminal<br />

boundary condition F (P, c, T ) = P (T ). Under our <strong>as</strong>sumption it holds<br />

⎡<br />

⎤<br />

F (P, c, T ) =<br />

( )<br />

P (T ) exp ⎢ 1 − e<br />

−κ(T −T )<br />

⎣ −c(T ) + A(T, T ) ⎥<br />

κ<br />

⎦<br />

} {{ }<br />

=0<br />

= P (T ).<br />

This proves Theorem 3.5.<br />

Thinking about real options under the purpose to find the optimal exercise moment<br />

for exploration ventures, brought up the thought of long term trends <strong>an</strong>d short term<br />

fluctuations in commodity markets. [Schwartz Smith 2000] used the idea <strong>an</strong>d pub-<br />

✷<br />

66


3.4 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Models<br />

lished their Long - Short Term Model that models me<strong>an</strong> reversion in short term<br />

prices <strong>an</strong>d uncertainty in the equilibrium level to which prices revert. Although,<br />

these variables are not directly observable in the market, the authors used the following<br />

intuition to estimate the parameters of the model from market data: movements<br />

in prices for long maturing futures contracts provide information about the<br />

equilibrium price level, <strong>an</strong>d differences between the prices for the short <strong>an</strong>d long<br />

term contracts provide information about short term variations. The mathematical<br />

formulation of the model is given in Definition 3.4.<br />

Definition 3.4 Long - Short Term Model<br />

Let P (t) be the spot price of a commodity at time t ∈ [0, T ], χ(t) the short-term<br />

deviation in prices at time t, ξ(t) the equilibrium price level at time t, µ ∈ R the<br />

drift of the equilibrium price level, κ > 0 the speed of adjustment of the short-term<br />

deviation, σ χ > 0 the short-term prices volatility, σ ξ > 0 the equilibrium price level<br />

volatility <strong>an</strong>d dW χ <strong>an</strong>d dW ξ the increments of two st<strong>an</strong>dard Browni<strong>an</strong> Motions <strong>as</strong><br />

defined in Definition C.28 with a correlation<br />

dW χ (t)dW ξ (t) = ρdt, t ∈ [0, T ], ρ ∈ [−1, 1]. (3.37)<br />

Then the dynamic of this model is<br />

ln P (t) = χ(t) + ξ(t) (3.38)<br />

dχ(t) = −κχ(t)dt + σ χ dW χ (t) (3.39)<br />

dξ(t) = µ ξ dt + σ ξ dW ξ (t), t ∈ [0, T ] (3.40)<br />

Temporary price ch<strong>an</strong>ges, caused e.g. by abrupt weather alteration or supply interruptions,<br />

are embodied in the short term component χ(t). They are not expected<br />

to persist because market particip<strong>an</strong>ts will switch to inventories to adjust ch<strong>an</strong>ging<br />

market conditions. Following [Gabillon 1995], production, consumption, stock level<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the fear of inventory disruptions are the most import<strong>an</strong>t expl<strong>an</strong>atory factors in<br />

the short run. Information of these factors are mainly needed for hedging purposes.<br />

Ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the long term level represent fundamental modifications of the market<br />

conditions <strong>an</strong>d are therefore, are expected to persist. Latter c<strong>an</strong> be caused e.g. by a<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ge in the number of producers in the industry or the availability of a commodity.<br />

It is also determined by expectations of exhausting supply, improving technology for<br />

the production <strong>an</strong>d macroeconomic influences like inflation, politics <strong>an</strong>d regulatory<br />

effects. Following [Gabillon 1995], the information is used for investment purposes.<br />

67


3 Pricing of Commodity Futures<br />

The derivation of the price of a futures contract with the underlying stoch<strong>as</strong>tic<br />

processes <strong>as</strong> of Definition 3.4 c<strong>an</strong> be found in [Schwartz Smith 2000]. Conceptually,<br />

its derivation runs <strong>as</strong> the methodology of Proof 3.4.1 <strong>an</strong>d Proof 3.4.2. To avoid<br />

redund<strong>an</strong>ce, we will focus on <strong>an</strong>other interesting fact. Although, the model does<br />

not explicitly consider ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the convenience yield, it is equivalent to the Convenience<br />

Yield Model of Definition 3.3. The following theorem gives the expl<strong>an</strong>ation<br />

how the variables of the one model c<strong>an</strong> be expressed <strong>as</strong> linear combination of the<br />

variables of the other model:<br />

Theorem 3.6 Equivalence of the Convenience Yield <strong>an</strong>d the Long - Short<br />

Term Model<br />

The Convenience Yield Model <strong>as</strong> of Definition 3.3 <strong>an</strong>d the Long - Short Model <strong>as</strong> of<br />

Definition 3.4 are equivalent with the following parameters:<br />

Long - Short Model<br />

κ<br />

σ χ<br />

Convenience Yield Model<br />

dW χ (t)<br />

dW c (t)<br />

µ ξ µ − α − 1 2 σ2 P<br />

σ ξ<br />

(σ P + σ2 c<br />

− 2ρσ κ 2 P σ c<br />

) 1 2<br />

κ<br />

dW ξ (t)<br />

ρ ξχ<br />

κ<br />

σ Pκ<br />

(σ P dW P (t) − σc<br />

κ dW c(t))(σ P + σ2 c<br />

κ 2 − 2ρσ P σ c<br />

κ<br />

) − 1 2<br />

(ρσ P − σc<br />

κ )(σ P + σ2 c<br />

κ 2 − 2ρσ P σ c<br />

κ<br />

) − 1 2<br />

Table 3.1: Equivalent Parameters<br />

Proof:<br />

Following Definition 3.3, the price dynamics in the two factor convenience<br />

yield model are given <strong>as</strong> of Equation (3.32) <strong>an</strong>d Equation (3.33):<br />

dP (t) = P (t)[µ − c(t)]dt + σ P P (t)dW P (t),<br />

dc(t) = κ[α − c(t)]dt + σ c dW c (t), t ∈ [0, T ]<br />

With Itô <strong>as</strong> of Lemma C.1 the log spot price dynamic of (3.32) are given <strong>as</strong>:<br />

dln(P (t)) =<br />

(( ) 1<br />

P (t)<br />

( 1<br />

+<br />

P (t)<br />

)<br />

(P (t)[µ − c(t)])<br />

)<br />

σ P P (t)dW P (t)<br />

dt + 0 + 1 2<br />

( ( )) −1<br />

σ P P (t) 2 dt<br />

P 2 (t)<br />

= [µ − c(t) − 1 2 σ2 P ]dt + σ P dW P (t) (3.41)<br />

68


3.4 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Models<br />

Then, the variables in the long - short model c<strong>an</strong> be written in terms of the variables<br />

of the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic convenience yield model <strong>as</strong> follows:<br />

χ(t) = short term deviation = 1 (c(t) − α)<br />

κ<br />

(3.42)<br />

Therewith, it follows<br />

Moreover<br />

dχ(t) = 1 κ dc(t)<br />

(3.33)<br />

{}}{<br />

= 1 κ (κ[α − c(t)]dt + σ cdW c (t))<br />

= [α − c(t)]dt + σ c<br />

κ dW c(t)<br />

(3.42)<br />

{}}{<br />

= −κχ(t)dt + σ c<br />

dW c (t)<br />

}{{} κ } {{ }<br />

≡dW<br />

≡σ χ(t)<br />

χ<br />

ξ(t) = equilibrium price level<br />

= ln(P (t)) − χ(t)<br />

= ln(P (t)) − 1 (c(t) − α) (3.43)<br />

κ<br />

Therewith, it follows<br />

dξ(t) = dln(P (t)) − 1 κ dc(t)<br />

= [µ − c(t) − 1 2 σ2 P ]dt + σ P dW P (t) − 1 κ (κ[α − c(t)]dt + σ cdW c (t))<br />

= [µ − α − 1 2 σ2 P ]dt + σ P dW P (t) − σ c<br />

} {{ }<br />

κ dW c(t)<br />

} {{ }<br />

≡µ ξ<br />

≡σ ξ ≡dW ξ (t)<br />

69


3 Pricing of Commodity Futures<br />

Finally,<br />

ρ ξχ dt = dW χ (t)dW ξ (t)<br />

= dW c (σ P dW P (t) − σ c<br />

κ dW c(t))(σ P + σ2 c<br />

κ − 2ρσ P σ c<br />

2 κ<br />

) − 1 2<br />

= (σ P dW P (t)dW<br />

} {{ } c − σ c<br />

κ dW c(t)dW c )(σ<br />

} {{ } P + σ2 c<br />

κ − 2ρσ P σ c<br />

2 κ<br />

=ρ P c dt<br />

=dt<br />

) − 1 2<br />

= (ρ P c σ P − σ c<br />

κ )dt(σ P + σ2 c<br />

κ − 2ρσ P σ c<br />

2 κ<br />

) − 1 2<br />

(3.44)<br />

showing the l<strong>as</strong>t equation of Table 3.1.<br />

✷<br />

[Schwartz Smith 2000] showed that the model works best for mid term maturities.<br />

Moreover, the model includes the two one factor models Browni<strong>an</strong> Motion <strong>an</strong>d Me<strong>an</strong><br />

Reversion. The first one is generated by setting σ χ equal to zero, i.e. <strong>as</strong>suming that<br />

there is uncertainty in equilibrium prices, only. A Me<strong>an</strong> Reversion Model is given<br />

by <strong>as</strong>suming a const<strong>an</strong>t equilibrium price, i.e. setting σ ξ equal to zero. Statistical<br />

comparison of the three models by the authors showed signific<strong>an</strong>t adv<strong>an</strong>tages in capturing<br />

the characteristics of commodity futures prices through the two factor model.<br />

But <strong>as</strong> [Lautier 2005] stats, there is still one question remaining: is it interesting to<br />

represent a stable equilibrium with a stoch<strong>as</strong>tic variable? On the other h<strong>an</strong>d, some<br />

pricing perspectives, especially in the real options environment, focus on long term<br />

prices <strong>an</strong>d do not care about short term fluctuation. 82<br />

3.4.3 Three Factor Models<br />

Not until 1997, the first three factor model w<strong>as</strong> introduced: [Schwartz 1997] proposed<br />

his three factor model with the extension of stoch<strong>as</strong>tic interest rates because<br />

the hypothesis of const<strong>an</strong>t interest rates <strong>as</strong> in the one <strong>an</strong>d two factor models amounts<br />

to saying that the term structure of interest rates is flat, which is far from reality.<br />

Moreover, under this <strong>as</strong>sumption forward <strong>an</strong>d futures prices are equivalent, which<br />

is not the c<strong>as</strong>e. 83<br />

With a stoch<strong>as</strong>tic interest rate, it is possible to determine two<br />

distinct payoff structures for forwards <strong>an</strong>d futures, i.e.<br />

to take into account the<br />

margin call mech<strong>an</strong>ism of the futures market. Finally, following [Lautier 2005], the<br />

82 Compare [Schwartz 1998].<br />

83 See [Pindyck 1994] <strong>an</strong>d [French 1983]. Compare Section 2.3.1.1 Paragraph ”Forwards <strong>an</strong>d Futures”.<br />

70


3.4 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Models<br />

presence of the interest rate <strong>as</strong> a third explicative factor is consistent with the theory<br />

of storage. When interest rates are high, storage is more expensive resulting into a<br />

reduction of inventory <strong>an</strong>d therewith, incre<strong>as</strong>ing the convenience yield.<br />

Definition 3.5 Convenience Yield Model<br />

Let P (t) be the spot price of a commodity at time t ∈ [0, T ], c(t) the convenience<br />

yield at time t, r(t) the interest rate at time t, µ ∈ R the drift of the spot price,<br />

α ∈ R is the long-run level to which the convenience yield reverts, m ∈ R is the<br />

long-run level to which the interest rate reverts, κ > 0 is the speed of adjustment<br />

of the convenience yield, β > 0 is the speed of adjustment of the interest rate,<br />

σ P > 0 the spot price volatility, σ c > 0 the convenience yield volatility, σ r > 0<br />

the interest rate volatility <strong>an</strong>d dW P (t), dW c (t) <strong>an</strong>d dW r (t) the increments of three<br />

Browni<strong>an</strong> Motions <strong>as</strong> defined in Definition C.28 with the following correlations:<br />

dW P (t)dW c (t) = ρ P c dt, dW c (t)dW r (t) = ρ cr dt <strong>an</strong>d dW r (t)dW P (t) = ρ rP dt, with<br />

t ∈ [0, T ] <strong>an</strong>d ρ ∈ [−1, 1]. The spot price, the inst<strong>an</strong>t<strong>an</strong>eous convenience yield <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the the inst<strong>an</strong>t<strong>an</strong>eous interest rate process are <strong>as</strong>sumed to have the following form:<br />

dP (t) = P (t)[µ − c(t)]dt + σ P P (t)dW P (t), (3.45)<br />

dc(t) = κ[α − c(t)]dt + σ c dW c (t), (3.46)<br />

dr(t) = β[m − r(t)]dt + σ r dW r (t), t ∈ [0, T ] (3.47)<br />

The stoch<strong>as</strong>tic factors in the models are the commodity spot price, the convenience<br />

yield <strong>an</strong>d the interest rate. By <strong>as</strong>suming a simple me<strong>an</strong> reverting process for the<br />

interest rate, it is possible to obtain a closed form solution for futures prices. Their<br />

derivation c<strong>an</strong> be found in [Schwartz 1997].<br />

A new approach comes from [Cortazar Schwartz 2003] <strong>as</strong> introduced in Definition 3.6.<br />

Again, the spot price <strong>an</strong>d the convenience yield are the first two risk factors but <strong>as</strong><br />

third they consider the long term spot price return, allowing it to be stoch<strong>as</strong>tic <strong>an</strong>d<br />

to return to a long term average. The temporary price variations are <strong>as</strong>sumed to be<br />

activated by ch<strong>an</strong>ges in inventory, where<strong>as</strong> the long term return is due to ch<strong>an</strong>ges<br />

in technologies, inflation or dem<strong>an</strong>d pattern. The dynamics are modeled <strong>as</strong> follows:<br />

Definition 3.6 The Long Term - Convenience Yield Model<br />

Let P (t) be the spot price of a commodity at time t ∈ [0, T ], y(t) the deme<strong>an</strong>ed<br />

convenience yield at time t, with y := c − α, where α is the long run me<strong>an</strong> of the<br />

convenience yield c, v(t) the expected long-term spot price return at time t, with v :=<br />

µ−α, where µ ∈ R is the drift of P , κ, a > 0 the speed of adjustments of the deme<strong>an</strong>ed<br />

convenience yield of v; ¯v ∈ R the long-run me<strong>an</strong> of the expected long-term spot price<br />

71


3 Pricing of Commodity Futures<br />

return, σ P , σ y , σ v > 0 the corresponding volatilities <strong>an</strong>d dW (t) P , dW (t) y , dW (t) v the<br />

increments of three st<strong>an</strong>dard Browni<strong>an</strong> Motions <strong>as</strong> defined in Definition C.28 with<br />

correlations ρ P y , ρ P v , ρ yv ∈ [−1, 1]. Then the dynamic of this model is<br />

dP (t) = P (t)[v(t) − y(t)]dt + σ P P (t)dW P (t), (3.48)<br />

dy(t) = −κy(t)dt + σ y dW y (t), (3.49)<br />

dv(t) = a[¯v − v(t)]dt + σ v dW v (t), t ∈ [0, T ]. (3.50)<br />

In practice, the development of three factor models deposit the question of sense<br />

<strong>an</strong>d usage. Although <strong>an</strong> empirical comparison of three factor to two factor models<br />

show that the introduction of a third factor improves the perform<strong>an</strong>ce of the models<br />

in terms of their ability to describe the evolution of futures prices, this improvement<br />

is too small to justify for higher computational costs. Especially, for the evaluation<br />

of more complex derivatives parsimony is needed. [Schwartz 1997] concludes, that<br />

the two factor Convenience Yield Model h<strong>as</strong> the best return on investment.<br />

72


4 Commodity Indices<br />

In the following section we will introduce the commodity trading vehicle our main<br />

focus is put on over the next sections: commodity indices. In traditional fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

markets, indices are <strong>as</strong>sumed to produce attractive risk <strong>an</strong>d return profiles. But<br />

what about commodity markets? Indeed, commodity indices represent diversified<br />

portfolios participating from the different facilities of their elements. 84 Recall, a<br />

commodity investment over a CTA also provides diversified commodity exposure.<br />

But the main difference between commodity indices <strong>an</strong>d m<strong>an</strong>aged futures accounts<br />

or funds is, that the indices introduced in this section represent long only, buy<br />

<strong>an</strong>d hold strategies whereby CTAs actively trade commodity derivatives, i.e. they<br />

are allowed to trade short positions for inst<strong>an</strong>ce. This yields to different risk <strong>an</strong>d<br />

return structures. [Schneeweiss Spurgin 1996] <strong>an</strong>alyzed various commodity indices<br />

<strong>an</strong>d indices which are used to track m<strong>an</strong>aged futures perform<strong>an</strong>ce. Results indicate<br />

that a buy <strong>an</strong>d hold commodity investment strategy provides a poor forec<strong>as</strong>t of CTA<br />

returns. Therefore, commodity indices have to be treated differently.<br />

Because commodity investment is still adolescent, there is only a very little amount<br />

of commodity indices of less th<strong>an</strong> 20 available. They differ among each other by<br />

e.g. number of commodities involved, their weighting <strong>an</strong>d rebal<strong>an</strong>cing procedures.<br />

The different characteristics are described in Section 4.1 <strong>an</strong>d shall serve us <strong>as</strong> a<br />

first warming up. The following Section 4.2 provides information about the major<br />

commodity indices. Most of them are not older th<strong>an</strong> ten to 15 years <strong>an</strong>d there are<br />

partly huge creation differences among them.<br />

Investors are accustomed <strong>an</strong>d attracted to the ability of entering a market via cheap<br />

diversified exposure yielding into <strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>ing dem<strong>an</strong>d for commodity linked products<br />

that will be introduced in Section 4.3. Products like mutual or exch<strong>an</strong>ge traded<br />

funds tracking <strong>an</strong> index are known from stock <strong>an</strong>d bond markets <strong>an</strong>d famous. Especially<br />

the fees are much lower th<strong>an</strong> m<strong>an</strong>aged futures fund fees that c<strong>an</strong> yield up<br />

to 25%.<br />

We already know from Section 3 the source of commodity futures return evolving in<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ges of the current supply <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d equilibriums. We will close this section<br />

in 4.4 by decomposing commodity index returns <strong>an</strong>d filtering their origins.<br />

84 In Section 5.1.3 we will give the mathematical expl<strong>an</strong>ation for this phenomena.<br />

73


4 Commodity Indices<br />

4.1 Characteristics<br />

A commodity index is designed to represent <strong>an</strong>d track price ch<strong>an</strong>ges in a b<strong>as</strong>ket of<br />

commodity futures contracts. The concept of <strong>an</strong> investable commodity index that is<br />

treated <strong>as</strong> a separate <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s w<strong>as</strong> first introduced in [Greer 1978]. The underlying<br />

logic is that the returns on the index approximate the returns to <strong>an</strong> investor holding<br />

a position in the <strong>as</strong>sets underlying b<strong>as</strong>ket. Following [Structured Products 2006] the<br />

difference between the different indexes is b<strong>as</strong>ed on a variety of design factors:<br />

4.1.1 Index Composition<br />

Commodity indices either include a narrow or a broad r<strong>an</strong>ge of single commodities.<br />

Narrow b<strong>as</strong>ed indices typically cover major commodities, primarily energy <strong>an</strong>d metals.<br />

They aim to be sector specific <strong>an</strong>d focus on liquid commodities with a direct link<br />

to industrial production <strong>an</strong>d GDP. Over this they seek to get exposure to factors<br />

such <strong>as</strong> weather conditions. In contr<strong>as</strong>t, broad b<strong>as</strong>ed indices cover a large variety of<br />

commodities that are economically signific<strong>an</strong>t including energy, metals <strong>an</strong>d agricultures.<br />

Although they are more difficult to replicate, they provide the investor with<br />

a diversified exposure because they take adv<strong>an</strong>tage of the low correlation between<br />

the different commodity groups. 85<br />

4.1.2 Index Weights<br />

The index weights determine the amount of a single commodity with which it enters<br />

the index. The determination methodology is unique <strong>an</strong>d b<strong>as</strong>ed on different factors.<br />

To get economic weights fundamental economic data such <strong>as</strong> world production are<br />

taken. Production of commodities c<strong>an</strong> be seen <strong>as</strong> the equivalent of market capitalization<br />

in stock markets that is taken to get the index weights of major stock<br />

indices. The e<strong>as</strong>iest way to create <strong>an</strong> index is to take fixed <strong>an</strong>d equal weights.<br />

There are some indices which weights calculation takes into account market factors.<br />

These include trading volume <strong>an</strong>d open interest of the respective commodity future<br />

contract. In the p<strong>as</strong>t some optimized weight schemes b<strong>as</strong>ed on econometric models<br />

were introduced. They seek to optimize criteria such <strong>as</strong> level of returns, volatility<br />

of returns or correlation to inflation.<br />

85 Further details see Section 5.1.2 <strong>an</strong>d 5.1.3.<br />

74


4.2 The Major Market Indices<br />

4.1.3 Rebal<strong>an</strong>cing<br />

Index rebal<strong>an</strong>cing includes two separate factors: the mech<strong>an</strong>ism of rolling futures<br />

contracts <strong>an</strong>d rebal<strong>an</strong>cing the portfolio weights. As described above futures are designed<br />

to mature after a predefined period. To enable long term investments in a<br />

single commodity the futures exposure h<strong>as</strong> to be tr<strong>an</strong>sferred, i.e. rolled over, from<br />

the maturing futures contract into a fairly long-term future contract. The chosen<br />

time lags (typically 1, 2 or three month) are different. The other element of index<br />

rebal<strong>an</strong>cing is the adjustment of the actual amount of futures contracts per commodity.<br />

The different indices have different rebal<strong>an</strong>cing <strong>an</strong>d roll over periods depending<br />

on the structure of the market they reflect. [Erb Harvey 2006] investigated the effect<br />

of rebal<strong>an</strong>cing <strong>an</strong>d show the import<strong>an</strong>ce of rebal<strong>an</strong>cing <strong>as</strong> a return driver.<br />

4.1.4 Return Calculation<br />

Returns may be calculated on <strong>an</strong> arithmetic or geometric b<strong>as</strong>is. The geometric average<br />

return calculation is a methodology which considers the compounded interest<br />

effect. A geometric average return is always smaller th<strong>an</strong> or equal to the arithmetic<br />

average return depending on the frequency of negative returns.<br />

4.1.5 Leveraged versus unleveraged Returns<br />

A leveraged commodity index also known <strong>as</strong> excess return index is b<strong>as</strong>ed on futures<br />

contracts. The terminology ”leveraged” reflects the fact that trading in futures<br />

requires minimal commitment of capital. Capital is just needed for margin requirements.<br />

To create indices which do not reflect a leverage effect the total amount<br />

invested in commodities have to be invested in collateral, typically in T-Bills. They<br />

are called total return indices <strong>an</strong>d provide the investor with unleveraged return. 86<br />

4.2 The Major Market Indices<br />

After structuring the different creation characteristics, we w<strong>an</strong>t to see what differences<br />

the most common market indices have among each other. The different<br />

creation characteristics such <strong>as</strong> index weighting or rebal<strong>an</strong>cing are driven by the<br />

two features of commodity markets: one being the trading platform for consumption<br />

goods <strong>an</strong>d one being the platform for fin<strong>an</strong>cial investments. The indices are<br />

86 Attention: The terminology ”leverage effect” describes in stock markets the correlation between<br />

falling prices <strong>an</strong>d rising volatility.<br />

75


4 Commodity Indices<br />

generally published in three categories: spot, excess <strong>an</strong>d total return. The spot<br />

return index is just a price index that replicates the underlying commodity spot<br />

price ch<strong>an</strong>ges. The excess return index replicates the underlying commodity futures<br />

price ch<strong>an</strong>ges so it includes gains <strong>an</strong>d losses from rolling maturing futures forward.<br />

Finally, the total return index represents a fully collateralized investment in the underlying<br />

commodity b<strong>as</strong>ket. Only the two l<strong>as</strong>t versions are investable because there<br />

does not exist a futures adequate spot market. 87 The r<strong>an</strong>ge of commodity indices is<br />

growing proportionally with the f<strong>as</strong>t growing dem<strong>an</strong>d for commodity linked investment<br />

possibilities but is still in size not comparable to the huge investment offers<br />

in stock <strong>an</strong>d bond markets. While in latter markets the available indices are nearly<br />

not countable, there are less th<strong>an</strong> 20 commodity indices launched. In the following<br />

paragraphs we will introduce the most market known ones <strong>an</strong>d closing this section<br />

with a small comparison of them.<br />

4.2.1 CRB<br />

The Commodity Research Bureau Index (CRM) index is the oldest of all commodity<br />

indices. It w<strong>as</strong> introduced in 1957 <strong>an</strong>d is reported in the CRB Yearbook. The index<br />

consists of 17 equally weighted commodities that are shown in Figure 4.1. It represents<br />

a broad b<strong>as</strong>ket of common commodity products. As the father of commodity<br />

indices <strong>an</strong>d because of its equal diversification it is widely viewed <strong>as</strong> a very good<br />

me<strong>as</strong>ure of macroeconomic trends.<br />

Figure 4.1: The CRB Index<br />

The index value is calculated with a double-averaging procedure which calculates<br />

87 For further details recall introduction to Section 3.<br />

76


4.2 The Major Market Indices<br />

first the geometric average return of the single relev<strong>an</strong>t commodities <strong>an</strong>d second, the<br />

geometric average return of the commodity b<strong>as</strong>ket. This makes the index robust<br />

against discontinuities <strong>as</strong>sociated with temporary supply <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d imbal<strong>an</strong>ces in<br />

a given month or commodity. 88<br />

Rebal<strong>an</strong>cing only takes place when the index c<strong>an</strong>’t ensure <strong>an</strong> accurate representation<br />

of the broad commodity market. There have been nine revisions to the component<br />

list, the l<strong>as</strong>t in 1995.<br />

Out of the investment point of view the index is a p<strong>as</strong>sive, ”buy-<strong>an</strong>d-hold” commodity<br />

futures b<strong>as</strong>ket. Signific<strong>an</strong>tly positive returns on this index typically occur<br />

when commodities are short in supply which is followed by rising commodity prices.<br />

This originates its reputation of being a macroeconomic trend me<strong>as</strong>ure.<br />

4.2.2 GSCI<br />

The Goldm<strong>an</strong> Sachs Commodity Index (GSCI) consists of 24 commodities <strong>an</strong>d is<br />

a me<strong>as</strong>ure of the perform<strong>an</strong>ce of actively traded, dollar-denominated nearby commodity<br />

futures. It w<strong>as</strong> first published in 1991, but the rule b<strong>as</strong>ed methodology w<strong>as</strong><br />

coupled with historical price data to create a history that begins at J<strong>an</strong>uary 1970<br />

with five commodities included. Therewith, the index h<strong>as</strong> the longest history of the<br />

commercially available indices.<br />

The weights of the index components are chosen <strong>as</strong> the 5 year moving average of<br />

their world production volume. Common equity indexes like the S&P 500 or the<br />

Eurostoxx 50 use the market capitalization of the comp<strong>an</strong>ies entering the index for<br />

the calculation of their component weights. This factor is seen <strong>as</strong> the equivalent to<br />

world production volume in commodity markets.<br />

Critics say that this puts to much weight to energy which is represented with over<br />

71% <strong>as</strong> shown in Figure 4.2. However, the choice of its components <strong>an</strong>d the weighting<br />

procedure allow the GSCI to reflect world economic growth.<br />

The GSCI weights are reviewed generally once a year. Since they are recalculated<br />

b<strong>as</strong>ed on world production which in turn is a function of produced qu<strong>an</strong>tities <strong>an</strong>d<br />

prices, ch<strong>an</strong>ges c<strong>an</strong> be heavy. For example, weights to reflect the Energy sector have<br />

varied in the p<strong>as</strong>t between 44% <strong>an</strong>d 73% of the index. 89<br />

88 See [Germ<strong>an</strong> 2005].<br />

89 See [Wilshire Research 2005].<br />

77


4 Commodity Indices<br />

Figure 4.2: The GSCI Index<br />

The Index h<strong>as</strong> a major drawback: If prices of a commodity rise, world production<br />

will rise <strong>as</strong> well because high cost producers are enabled to enter the market. If world<br />

production rises, the GSCI puts more weight to this commodities. But commodity<br />

prices tend to me<strong>an</strong> revert to a long term price level. 90 Implicating the GSCI takes<br />

to much weight into commodities which are expected to fall in price over the coming<br />

periods.<br />

4.2.3 DJ-AIGCI<br />

The Dow Jones - Americ<strong>an</strong> International Group Commodity Index (DJ-AIGCI) w<strong>as</strong><br />

designed in 1998 with a backfilled history until 1991 to be a liquid benchmark for<br />

commodity investments. To calculate the weights of its 19 components shown in<br />

Figure 4.3 it takes two me<strong>as</strong>urements into consideration: production <strong>an</strong>d liquidity,<br />

whereby liquidity is the domin<strong>an</strong>t factor. From the fin<strong>an</strong>cial point of view, further<br />

is <strong>an</strong> exogenous qu<strong>an</strong>tity of futures markets reflecting the consumption good<br />

character of commodities <strong>an</strong>d latter is <strong>an</strong> endogenous qu<strong>an</strong>tity of futures markets<br />

reflecting the investment character of commodities. Like explained for the GSCI,<br />

production is a useful me<strong>as</strong>ure of economic import<strong>an</strong>ce but may underestimate the<br />

economic signific<strong>an</strong>ce of storable commodities (e.g. gold) in comparison to nonstorable<br />

commodities (e.g. live cattle). To compensate this, liquidity comes up. It<br />

is <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t indicator for the current value placed on a commodity by fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

<strong>an</strong>d physical market particip<strong>an</strong>ts.<br />

The index weights are reviewed <strong>an</strong>d recalculated once a year by the DJ-AIGCI’s<br />

90 See [Bessembinder e.a. 1995].<br />

78


4.2 The Major Market Indices<br />

Figure 4.3: The DJ-AIGCI Index<br />

Oversight Committee. Ch<strong>an</strong>ges are less dr<strong>as</strong>tic th<strong>an</strong> in the GSCI because there<br />

exists minimum (2%) <strong>an</strong>d maximum (33%) limits to restrict the weights for single<br />

commodities <strong>an</strong>d sectors.<br />

4.2.4 DBLCI<br />

The Deutsche B<strong>an</strong>k Liquid Commodity Index (DBLCI) is relatively different to the<br />

other indices. As shown in Figure 4.4 it just includes six of the most liquid commodity<br />

futures in terms of trading volume <strong>an</strong>d open interest where<strong>as</strong> the other indices<br />

include between 17 to 34 constituents. In 2003, Deutsche B<strong>an</strong>k research <strong>an</strong>alyzed<br />

the GSCI. They showed that the volatility of a commodity b<strong>as</strong>ket depends of the<br />

number of its constituents <strong>an</strong>d decided that there is no need for more th<strong>an</strong> a couple<br />

of single commodities to get the volatility converging against a const<strong>an</strong>t fixed<br />

value. Therefore, they decided that six commodities which are chosen out of the big<br />

commodity groups energy, metal <strong>an</strong>d agriculture are enough to present commodity<br />

markets optimally. 91 Figure 4.4 shows the composition of the index. One big adv<strong>an</strong>tage<br />

of the index is that it is e<strong>as</strong>y to track because the component weights are<br />

not volatile.<br />

4.2.5 DBLCI-MR<br />

The Deutsche B<strong>an</strong>k Liquid Commodity Index - Me<strong>an</strong> Reversion (DBLCI-MR) includes<br />

the same components <strong>as</strong> the DBLCI. The difference is that the weights of its<br />

91 For further details see Section 5.1.3.<br />

79


4 Commodity Indices<br />

Figure 4.4: The DBLCI Index<br />

components are updated relatively to its five year price moving average. Because<br />

commodity prices tend to me<strong>an</strong> revert over time against a long term price these<br />

averaging methodology h<strong>as</strong> the feature of being <strong>an</strong> early signal. If a commodity is<br />

cheap relative to its five year moving average price, the index weight gets incre<strong>as</strong>ed.<br />

If it is relatively expensive, it gets reduced. As shown in [Bessembinder e.a. 1995]<br />

this methodology is not very useful. The drawback is that the me<strong>an</strong> reversion effect<br />

of the commodity prices is slow. The index reacts directly. Thus, there is no gain<br />

taking over long periods. It c<strong>an</strong> be seen in Figure 4.5 that although energy futures<br />

are still running extraordinary, the DBLCI-MR reduced the energy weight already<br />

<strong>an</strong>d profit taking’s capacity is not fully used.<br />

Figure 4.5: The DBLCI-MR Index<br />

Ple<strong>as</strong>e note that the weights of the DBLCI-MR are very volatile. At the moment<br />

the main weight is put to agricultures because they are cheap in comparison to their<br />

80


4.2 The Major Market Indices<br />

five year moving average price. In other periods crude <strong>an</strong>d heating oil had weights<br />

around 30%. This makes it expensive to track the index.<br />

4.2.6 RICI<br />

The Rogers International Commodity Index (RICI) w<strong>as</strong> launched in 1998 by the<br />

Wall Street legend Jim Rogers who entered the guiness book of records in the 1970s<br />

with his Qu<strong>an</strong>tum Fund <strong>as</strong> best performing fund ever. The investment approach<br />

Jim Rogers always takes is a macroeconomic one. He tries to reflect global economic<br />

developments. Therefore, the 34 components <strong>an</strong>d its weights are chosen to<br />

reflect their import<strong>an</strong>ce in international commerce. Jim Rogers mentioned in his<br />

book: ”The RICI represents my version of the world, it reflects the costs of life <strong>an</strong>d<br />

survival.” 92<br />

Figure 4.6: The RICI Index<br />

The index is rebal<strong>an</strong>ced monthly. Research h<strong>as</strong> shown that monthly rebal<strong>an</strong>cing<br />

provides <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>nualized return adv<strong>an</strong>tage of 1.5% to 2% in comparison to <strong>an</strong>nually<br />

rebal<strong>an</strong>cing. 93<br />

4.2.7 Comparison of the Major Market Indices<br />

Closing this section we will give a small comparison of the introduced indices.<br />

Table 4.1 summarizes their major characteristics clearly arr<strong>an</strong>ged, including index<br />

comparison, major groups <strong>as</strong> of Figure 2.1, number of integrated commodities, index<br />

92 See [Rogers 2005].<br />

93 See [Erb Harvey 2006] or [Seam<strong>an</strong>s 2003].<br />

81


4 Commodity Indices<br />

weights, its determination, the rebal<strong>an</strong>cing period <strong>an</strong>d the return calculation.<br />

Index<br />

Composition<br />

CRB GSCI DJ-AIGCI DBLCI DBLCI-MR RICI<br />

broad broad broad broad broad broad<br />

Major Groups 94 all all all<br />

Number of<br />

<strong>Commodities</strong><br />

no Softs, no<br />

Livestock<br />

no Softs, no<br />

Livestock<br />

17 24 19 5 5 34<br />

Index Weights equal economic<br />

Determination<br />

of Weights<br />

economic,<br />

market<br />

all<br />

fix optimized economic<br />

if required <strong>an</strong>nually <strong>an</strong>nually if required monthly <strong>an</strong>nually<br />

Rebal<strong>an</strong>cing monthly <strong>an</strong>nually <strong>an</strong>nually <strong>an</strong>nually monthly monthly<br />

Return<br />

Calculation<br />

geometric arithmetic arithmetic arithmetic arithmetic arithmetic<br />

Table 4.1: Comparison of Commodity Index Characteristics<br />

We only introduced broad diversified indices to reach better comparability. Economic<br />

index weights like production <strong>an</strong>d consumption are most mentioned <strong>an</strong>d<br />

reflect commodity’s role <strong>as</strong> consumption good. Moreover, some indices are more<br />

dynamic th<strong>an</strong> other, e.g. rebal<strong>an</strong>cing takes place monthly instead of <strong>an</strong>nually <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the determination of weights r<strong>an</strong>ges from if required to monthly. This fact h<strong>as</strong> to<br />

be considered in index tracking purposes when e.g. tr<strong>an</strong>saction costs come up.<br />

Moreover, it becomes clear that there are differences of the amount of different single<br />

commodities integrated in the different indices r<strong>an</strong>ging from five in the DBLCI <strong>an</strong>d<br />

DBLCI-MR to 34 integrated into the RICI. To reach <strong>an</strong> even better comparison of<br />

the index ingredients we aggregate the single constituencies into their major groups<br />

following Figure 2.1. The result c<strong>an</strong> be seen in Figure 4.7.<br />

We realize that not only the number of commodities differ between the indices but<br />

also their weighting regarding the three major commodity groups. The GSCI <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the DBLCI have over weight in the energy sector while the CRB h<strong>as</strong> over weight<br />

in the agricultural group indicating that the characteristics of these sub markets<br />

will dominate the whole risk <strong>an</strong>d return profile of the respective index. The best<br />

diversified index with nearly one third of its weights in each commodity group is the<br />

DJ-AIGCI. Therefore, we picked it for the further <strong>an</strong>alyzes.<br />

93 As of Figure 2.1.<br />

82


4.3 Index Linked Products<br />

Figure 4.7: Index Component Distribution<br />

4.3 Index Linked Products<br />

Today, commodity indices represent the e<strong>as</strong>iest way to get diversified commodity<br />

exposure. The direct way is to use linked derivatives like futures <strong>an</strong>d options. But<br />

this includes caring about maturities <strong>an</strong>d m<strong>an</strong>y investors are long term orientated<br />

<strong>an</strong>d therefore, do not w<strong>an</strong>t to go down this street. Mutual funds tracking the<br />

perform<strong>an</strong>ce of major commodity indices are en vogue because it is a simple way<br />

to get a broad commodity portfolio in a convenient way. Furthermore, the product<br />

r<strong>an</strong>ge w<strong>as</strong> extended by introducing certificates <strong>an</strong>d exch<strong>an</strong>ge traded funds recently.<br />

In the following sections we w<strong>an</strong>t to take a look at the f<strong>as</strong>t growing commodity index<br />

linked investment opportunities including derivatives in Section 4.3.1, mutual funds<br />

in Section 4.3.2 <strong>an</strong>d exch<strong>an</strong>ge traded funds in Section 4.3.3.<br />

4.3.1 Derivatives<br />

Generally, you c<strong>an</strong> get everything over-the-counter (OTC) <strong>as</strong> long <strong>as</strong> you find <strong>an</strong><br />

adequate dealer. Especially swaps <strong>an</strong>d index linked notes are preferred more <strong>an</strong>d<br />

more to get commodity index exposure. In contr<strong>as</strong>t, exch<strong>an</strong>ge traded products are<br />

rare. There are future contracts maturing every J<strong>an</strong>uary, February, April, June,<br />

August, October, <strong>an</strong>d December listed at the Chicago Board of Trade (CBOT) to<br />

trade the DJ-AIGCI. Each individual futures contract h<strong>as</strong> a fixed ratio to the index<br />

value of DJ-AIGCI, <strong>an</strong>d investors c<strong>an</strong> e<strong>as</strong>ily estimate the fair value for each DJ-<br />

AIGCI futures contract on a live b<strong>as</strong>is, b<strong>as</strong>ed on the prices of the underlying futures<br />

contracts which are used to calculate the DJ-AIGCI.<br />

The GSCI h<strong>as</strong> futures contracts listed on the Chicago Merc<strong>an</strong>tile Exch<strong>an</strong>ge (CME)<br />

that have been traded by numerous market makers for over 12 years. The GSCI<br />

83


4 Commodity Indices<br />

is the most liquid commodity index because the maturities are monthly. Over this<br />

there c<strong>an</strong> be traded a long term futures contract maturing in May 2011.<br />

Since 2005 a so-called Rogers TRAKRS future c<strong>an</strong> be traded at the CME. The<br />

exch<strong>an</strong>ge in collaboration with Merrill Lynch created a RICI tracking portfolio what<br />

c<strong>an</strong> be accessed by investors through a futures contract with long run maturity until<br />

2010.<br />

For the Deutsche B<strong>an</strong>k Indices all possible OTC products are available. Moreover,<br />

Deutsche B<strong>an</strong>k offers OTC swaps, forwards, linked notes <strong>an</strong>d options to get<br />

DJ-AIGCI <strong>an</strong>d GSCI exposure.<br />

In 2005 UBS w<strong>as</strong> the first issuer who offered different types of certificates with the<br />

RICI <strong>as</strong> underlying.<br />

4.3.2 Mutual Funds<br />

Comparing the number of available commodity linked mutual funds with the total<br />

amount of available equity linked funds one would be very surprised. On the commodity<br />

linked side we have less th<strong>an</strong> 20 funds available but on the equity side the<br />

fund horizon seems to be endless. Not until 1997 <strong>as</strong> the Oppenheimer Real <strong>Asset</strong><br />

Fund w<strong>as</strong> launched, people started doing business in this investment field. Today,<br />

there are approximately 15 billion US dollar of <strong>as</strong>sets under m<strong>an</strong>agement, this is<br />

more th<strong>an</strong> 10% of the money invested in the m<strong>an</strong>aged futures business but less th<strong>an</strong><br />

0.1% of the total money invested worldwide in mutual funds. 94<br />

Generally commodity linked mutual funds do not build up a futures portfolio to track<br />

a commodity index. They get commodity exposure over commodity linked notes or<br />

swaps. The latter ones were very common until <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>nouncement of the Internal<br />

Revenue Service 95 that income from commodity-linked swaps is not a ”qu<strong>an</strong>tifying<br />

income” because the underlying instruments were not securities.<br />

As a result, a<br />

mutual fund that is invested in commodity swaps with more th<strong>an</strong> 10% of its gross<br />

income would lose its status <strong>as</strong> a registered investment comp<strong>an</strong>y, <strong>an</strong>d would become<br />

taxable for income <strong>an</strong>d capital gains, rather th<strong>an</strong> p<strong>as</strong>sing taxes through to their<br />

investors. From July 2006 on, there will be a huge move out of swaps into structured<br />

notes.<br />

Whatever linked derivative are taken to get a commodity investment, the funds exposure<br />

is usually indirect. But at the end of the day their buying power shows up<br />

94 See [ICI 2006]<br />

95 The Internal Revenue Service (IRS) is the US government agency responsible for tax collection<br />

<strong>an</strong>d tax law enforcement.<br />

84


4.3 Index Linked Products<br />

in commodity futures markets: When the major derivatives issuers, e.g. Goldm<strong>an</strong><br />

Sachs or AIG Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Products, sell OTC commodity linked derivatives to the<br />

mutual funds, they end up short. To hedge their books, issuers turn around <strong>an</strong>d<br />

buy through own trading desks or external traders equivalent futures to reset their<br />

positions <strong>as</strong> shown in Figure 2.18. The resulting construct is complex but everybody<br />

is satisfied: investors get commodity exposure through a familiar investment<br />

vehicle, mutual fund comp<strong>an</strong>ies incre<strong>as</strong>e their <strong>as</strong>sets under m<strong>an</strong>agement, derivatives<br />

dealers earn fees by selling commodity linked derivatives <strong>an</strong>d replicating the index<br />

<strong>an</strong>d futures industry benefits from higher trading volume. To make thinks more<br />

pl<strong>as</strong>tic Table 4.2 summarizes the major mutual funds available in July 2006.<br />

Fund Name Index NAV Mil.US dollar<br />

Pimco Commodity Real Return Strategy DJ-AIGCI 11,823<br />

Oppenheimer Real <strong>Asset</strong> Fund GSCI 1,900<br />

Fidelity Strategic Real Return Fund DJ-AIGCI 1,934<br />

Credit Suisse Commodity Return Strategy DJ-AIGCI 277<br />

DWS Scudder Commodity Securities Fund GSCI 183<br />

Table 4.2: Commodity Index linked Mutual Funds<br />

Combining the Net <strong>Asset</strong> Values 96 (NAVs) of the above mentioned mutual funds<br />

the PIMCO Commodity Real Return Fund is by far the biggest flagship. It w<strong>as</strong><br />

introduced in 2002 <strong>an</strong>d is consequently the second oldest behind Oppenheimer’s<br />

Real <strong>Asset</strong> Fund. It combines a position in commodity futures backed primarily by<br />

a portfolio of inflation linked interest products. Hereby, the commodity exposure is<br />

p<strong>as</strong>sively m<strong>an</strong>aged to track the DJ-AIGCI <strong>an</strong>d the fixed income collateral portfolio<br />

is m<strong>an</strong>aged actively. At the beginning of July 2006 PIMCO published that they<br />

shift there commodity exposure out of swaps into linked notes <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> reaction to the<br />

above mentioned ch<strong>an</strong>ge in regulatory requirements. 97<br />

An example of <strong>an</strong> actively m<strong>an</strong>aged commodity fund is the Oppenheimer real <strong>as</strong>set<br />

fund which w<strong>as</strong> launched in 1997 <strong>an</strong>d thus w<strong>as</strong> the first Real <strong>Asset</strong> Fund ever. Its<br />

purpose is to outperform the GSCI. The fund holds approximately one third of its<br />

<strong>as</strong>sets in structured notes linked to the GSCI. In addition, the portfolio includes<br />

subst<strong>an</strong>tial direct holdings of futures contracts, at the moment 8.2% of its total<br />

<strong>as</strong>sets in energy futures, 3.4% in metals <strong>an</strong>d 2.1% in agricultures.<br />

The Fidelity Strategic Real Return Fund w<strong>as</strong> launched in September 2005 to provide<br />

96 The Net <strong>Asset</strong> Value is defined <strong>as</strong> the difference between total <strong>as</strong>sets minus total liabilities.<br />

97 See http : \ \ www.alli<strong>an</strong>zinvestors.com \ commentary \ edu education02072006.jsp<br />

85


4 Commodity Indices<br />

its investors ”with <strong>an</strong> inflation linked security” what is backed out of 17.3% real<br />

estate investments, 30.5% inflation protected investments, 24.7% floating rate high<br />

yield, 25.2% commodity linked notes <strong>an</strong>d 2.3% c<strong>as</strong>h. The commodity exposure is<br />

build up with structured notes currently to the DJ-AIGCI.<br />

In J<strong>an</strong>uary 2005 Credit Suisse launched its Commodity Return Fund which primarily<br />

invests in commodity linked swaps which make it receiving a total return rate b<strong>as</strong>ed<br />

on the DJ-AIGCI <strong>an</strong>d make it paying the 1 month U.S. Tre<strong>as</strong>ury Bill rate plus<br />

a spread. 98 The portfolio is backed by investment-grade fixed income securities<br />

normally having <strong>an</strong> average duration of one year or less.<br />

The DWS Scubber Commodity Securities Fund w<strong>as</strong> launched in February 2005. The<br />

fund’s benchmark comprises 50% of the GSCI, 25% of the MSCI World Energy <strong>an</strong>d<br />

25% of the MSCI World Materials Index. Therefore, it’s composed out of 50% commodity<br />

related common stocks <strong>an</strong>d 50% commodity related structured notes. The<br />

fund uses both top-down <strong>an</strong>alysis to decide which sectors to over- or underweight<br />

b<strong>as</strong>ed on the supply <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d picture <strong>an</strong>d other fundamental trends in commodity<br />

markets <strong>an</strong>d bottom-up research to pick promising individual comp<strong>an</strong>ies. It<br />

invests into the GSCI through linked notes, swap agreements <strong>an</strong>d futures contracts.<br />

It is eye-catching that the market is strongly dominated by the GSCI <strong>an</strong>d the DJ-<br />

AIGCI. These two indices are the oldest investable commodity indices <strong>an</strong>d have<br />

therefore not only a long tradition but are well known in the fin<strong>an</strong>cial investment<br />

sector. Because investing in commodities <strong>as</strong> a retail process is quite young <strong>an</strong>d new<br />

products have to be set up. Nevertheless, this market is very active <strong>an</strong>d specially<br />

the RICI is getting more popular. Uhlm<strong>an</strong>n Price Security w<strong>as</strong> the first provider<br />

which enabled investors to get RICI exposure over a mutual fund. In Europe UBS<br />

Investments offers a mutual fund with RICI <strong>as</strong> benchmark.<br />

4.3.3 Exch<strong>an</strong>ge Traded Funds<br />

Exch<strong>an</strong>ge Traded Funds (ETFs) are a relatively recent innovative investment concept<br />

<strong>an</strong>d were first introduced in 1993. They represent exch<strong>an</strong>ge traded investment<br />

funds which in the c<strong>as</strong>e of commodities invest long in fully collateralized futures<br />

positions. In comparison to traditional mutual funds ETS’ are perm<strong>an</strong>ently traded<br />

like stocks. Therefore, ETFs combine the flexibility of stocks with the risk control<br />

over diversification of traditional mutual funds: <strong>an</strong>y investor c<strong>an</strong> buy or sell shares<br />

98 Regarding the ch<strong>an</strong>ge in regulatory guidelines a redeployment into commodity linked notes c<strong>an</strong><br />

be expected.<br />

86


4.3 Index Linked Products<br />

in ETFs, at a price that is a close approximation of the net <strong>as</strong>set value per share, 99<br />

from virtually <strong>an</strong>y broker, <strong>an</strong>d need not wait for end-of-day pricing or worry about<br />

trading discounts to NAV. Over this, the m<strong>an</strong>agement fees are generally much lower<br />

then the fees of mutual funds <strong>an</strong>d commodity pools. In the 13 years since their<br />

introduction, the number of ETF’s h<strong>as</strong> grown to 200 listed at Americ<strong>an</strong> stock exch<strong>an</strong>ges<br />

with <strong>an</strong> amount of 300 billion US dollar under m<strong>an</strong>agement at the end of<br />

2005. 100<br />

The first ETF with commodity focus w<strong>as</strong> listed in February 2006 on the Americ<strong>an</strong><br />

Stock Exch<strong>an</strong>ge under the symbol DBC st<strong>an</strong>ding for DB Commodity Index Tracking<br />

Fund. The fund’s objective is to track the DBLCI Excess Return. Because the<br />

fund is not actively m<strong>an</strong>aged there is a very low fee of 1.3% <strong>an</strong>nually, including<br />

m<strong>an</strong>agement <strong>an</strong>d brokerage fees. In comparison, mutual fund m<strong>an</strong>agement fees are<br />

much higher: there is generally a 5% purch<strong>as</strong>ing fee plus <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>nual m<strong>an</strong>agement<br />

fee.<br />

The DBC utilizes a two-tier structure, i.e it invests its <strong>as</strong>sets in a m<strong>as</strong>ter fund<br />

which is fully owned by Deutsche B<strong>an</strong>k AG. The m<strong>as</strong>ter fund, in turn, invests its<br />

<strong>as</strong>sets in exch<strong>an</strong>ge traded futures on the commodity respectively its weights in the<br />

DBLCI <strong>an</strong>d a small amount into U.S. Tre<strong>as</strong>ury securities to serve margin payments.<br />

This operation method is totally different from that of mutual funds <strong>as</strong> they get<br />

commodity exposure indirect through swaps <strong>an</strong>d linked notes. Although the fund<br />

h<strong>as</strong> been available for only a few months, it already attracted subst<strong>an</strong>tial interest<br />

from retail investors. Net <strong>as</strong>sets at the end of April 2006, were approximately 400<br />

million US dollar what is almost twice the size of the one year old Credit Suisse<br />

Commodity Return Strategy Fund.<br />

The DBC h<strong>as</strong> set a milestone in commodity investments <strong>an</strong>d it c<strong>an</strong> be expected<br />

that other commodity pools will replicate this concept <strong>an</strong>d list their shares via <strong>an</strong><br />

ETF type structure. One follower w<strong>as</strong> ABN AMRO in May 2006. It listed the<br />

shares of <strong>an</strong> ETF which tracks the perform<strong>an</strong>ce of the RICI on Deutsche Börse.<br />

The big adv<strong>an</strong>tage is that investors will have the opportunity to obtain exposure<br />

to the commodities markets in a format that provides unprecedented tr<strong>an</strong>sparency,<br />

liquidity <strong>an</strong>d cost-effectiveness.<br />

99 The NAV per share is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

100 See [ICI 2006]<br />

NAV per share =<br />

total <strong>as</strong>sets - total liabilities<br />

total number of shares outst<strong>an</strong>ding<br />

87


4 Commodity Indices<br />

4.4 Decomposition of Index Returns<br />

In this section we will get a deeper insight into the return structure of commodity<br />

indices. As already mentioned introductory to Section 4.1 there are three different<br />

index types calculated by the index issuer: the total return index, representing the<br />

return development of a fully collateralized commodity investment, the excess return<br />

index, representing the return development of a leveraged commodity investment,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the spot return index, representing the simple commodity price ch<strong>an</strong>ges over<br />

time. But how are the three types connected to each other? Figure 4.8 shall give a<br />

first overview of their team play. 101<br />

Total Return = Excess Return + Interest Rate Return<br />

✘ ✘✘ ✘ ✘✘ ✘❳❳ ❳❳<br />

❳ ❳❳<br />

Spot Return + Roll Return<br />

Figure 4.8: Decomposition of Commodity Index Return<br />

A single <strong>as</strong>set’s index is nothing else but a time series of the prices realized by the<br />

underlying <strong>as</strong>set. In stock markets this equals a buy <strong>an</strong>d hold trading strategy. In<br />

commodity markets it is not that e<strong>as</strong>y because commodities are traded with futures<br />

contracts, i.e.<br />

the underlying h<strong>as</strong> a maturity <strong>an</strong>d therefore, investments have to<br />

be rolled over different positions by <strong>an</strong>d by resulting in the so-called futures or<br />

excess return <strong>as</strong> the pure return produced by commodity investments. It depends<br />

of the actual price ch<strong>an</strong>ges of the underlying commodity covered in the spot return<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the roll return realized by rolling futures positions forward under the current<br />

term structure. Later in this section we will see the mathematical derivation of this<br />

dependence structure in Theorem 4.1.<br />

The most common way to construct a single commodity index is to roll someone’s<br />

position from the first to the nearest longer term contract because the nearby contracts<br />

have generally the highest liquidity. Futures investments need minimal c<strong>as</strong>h<br />

requirements that are only used to serve margin calls. But to actually add commodities<br />

<strong>as</strong> part of <strong>an</strong> investment portfolio someone h<strong>as</strong> actually to invest a certain<br />

amount reserved for commodity investment. Because this is not possible with fu-<br />

101 Figure 4.8 <strong>an</strong>d the following calculations are b<strong>as</strong>ed on log returns <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.2. Compare<br />

[Kat Oomen 2006]. For a commodity return decomposition b<strong>as</strong>ed on simple returns see<br />

[Geer 2000].<br />

88


4.4 Decomposition of Index Returns<br />

tures contracts, someone h<strong>as</strong> to invest the reserved amount into a reference <strong>as</strong>set<br />

called collateral. The issuers of the main indices usually use T-Bills producing historically<br />

<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>nualized return of 3-4%. Because log returns are additive, 102 the first<br />

decomposition of Figure 4.8 of total return into excess <strong>an</strong>d interest rate return is<br />

quite intuitive. But what about the second decomposition of excess return into spot<br />

<strong>an</strong>d roll return?<br />

To <strong>an</strong>swer this question we will first give <strong>an</strong> example calculation by constructing the<br />

futures return time series by rolling the maturing contract into the next nearby contract<br />

for the crude oil <strong>an</strong>d copper futures contract already known from in Figure 3.2<br />

in Section 3.1 <strong>an</strong>d second derive the mathematical illustration in Theorem 4.1. For<br />

it, Table 4.3 <strong>an</strong>d Table 4.5 summarize the price movements of the respective contracts.<br />

The column header give the maturity T of the respective contract <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

raw header the respective date t at which the price of the contract is me<strong>as</strong>ured.<br />

The respective spot return time series is constructed by using the price of the front<br />

month futures contract <strong>as</strong> a proxy. 103 The respective values are highlighted by bold<br />

letters.<br />

Crude Oil (US dollar) J<strong>an</strong> 06 Feb 06 Mar 06 Apr 06 May 06 Jun 06 Jul 06<br />

30. Dec 2005 57.98 →61.04 ↓<br />

31.09 62.35 62.70 63.00 63.25<br />

31. J<strong>an</strong> 2006 68.35 →67.92 ↓<br />

68.74 69.28 69.70 70.01<br />

28. Feb 2006 61.10 →61.41 ↓<br />

63.01 64.06 64.83<br />

31. Mar 2006 60.57 →66.63 ↓<br />

67.93 68.67<br />

28. Apr 2006 71.95 → 71.88 ↓<br />

73.50<br />

31. May 2006 69.23 →71.29 ↓<br />

30. Jun 2006 68.94<br />

Table 4.3: Construction of a Futures Return Series for Crude Oil<br />

First, we will examine the construction of a futures return series exemplified by<br />

the crude oil price series.<br />

The construction follows the arrows in Table 4.3 <strong>an</strong>d<br />

is b<strong>as</strong>ed on the following thought: From the end of November 2005 to the end of<br />

December 2005 the investor holds the J<strong>an</strong>uary 2006 contract. Before the contract<br />

expires in J<strong>an</strong>uary 2006 he closes his position <strong>an</strong>d at the same time he opens a new<br />

position in the February 2006 contract which he holds until the end of J<strong>an</strong>uary 2006.<br />

Following Definition C.2 the futures return is given <strong>as</strong>:<br />

r F (t) ≡ ln<br />

( ) F (t, T )<br />

, 0 ≤ s < t ≤ T<br />

F (s, T )<br />

102 See Theorem 4.1.<br />

103 The procedure is inspired by [Markert 2005] <strong>an</strong>d [Gorton Rouwenhorst 2004].<br />

89


4 Commodity Indices<br />

Implicating, the investor realizes a crude oil futures return of:<br />

r F (J<strong>an</strong>) = ln<br />

( ) ( )<br />

F (J<strong>an</strong>, F eb) 68.35<br />

= ln = 11.3%<br />

F (Dec, F eb) 61.04<br />

Again, before the contract expires he closes his February 2006 position <strong>an</strong>d opens<br />

a position in the March 2006 contract. The crude oil futures return time series is<br />

continued with the following value:<br />

r F (F eb) = ln<br />

( ) ( )<br />

F (F eb, Mar) 61.10<br />

= ln = −10.6%<br />

F (J<strong>an</strong>, Mar) 67.92<br />

Running the described construction methodology over the reported times a whole<br />

futures return time series evolves. The results are reported in the first column of<br />

Table 4.4 <strong>an</strong>d also known <strong>as</strong> excess return <strong>as</strong> of Figure 4.8.<br />

The next step to encode the different futures return elements is to construct the spot<br />

return. We use the bold highlighted prices in Table 4.3 because the front month<br />

futures contract serves <strong>as</strong> proxy. Following Definition C.2 the spot return is given<br />

<strong>as</strong>:<br />

r P (t) ≡ ln<br />

( ) P (t)<br />

, 0 ≤ s < t ≤ T<br />

P (s)<br />

Implicating, the first crude oil spot return value is given by:<br />

r P (J<strong>an</strong>) = ln<br />

The second value is gives by:<br />

r P (F eb) = ln<br />

( ) ( )<br />

P (J<strong>an</strong>) 68.35<br />

= ln = 16.5%<br />

P (Dec) 57.98<br />

( ) ( )<br />

P (F eb) 61.10<br />

= ln = −11.2%<br />

P (J<strong>an</strong>) 68.35<br />

Again, running the described calculation rule over the reported times a whole spot<br />

return time series evolves. All values are listed in the second column of Table 4.4.<br />

Although crude oil went up in price over the l<strong>as</strong>t months <strong>an</strong>d could realize a high spot<br />

return the positive slope of the term structure <strong>as</strong> shown in Figure 3.2 disembogue<br />

into a negative difference between futures <strong>an</strong>d spot returns over the whole period <strong>as</strong><br />

documented in the l<strong>as</strong>t column of Table 4.4. This gap is caused by rolling a maturing<br />

futures contract into the next nearby month futures contract. Because the market<br />

is in cont<strong>an</strong>go the next nearby month futures contract is more expensive th<strong>an</strong> the<br />

maturing futures contract <strong>an</strong>d the investor realizes a loss amounting to -17.4% by<br />

90


4.4 Decomposition of Index Returns<br />

Future Return Spot Return Difference = Roll Return<br />

J<strong>an</strong> 2006 11.3% 16.5% -5.1%<br />

Feb 2006 -10.6% -11.2% 0.6%<br />

Mar 2006 -1.4% -0.9% -0.5%<br />

Apr 2006 7.7% 17.2% -9.5%<br />

May 2006 -3.8% -3.9% 0.1%<br />

Jun 2006 -3.4% -0.4% -2.9%<br />

Total -0.1% 17.3% -17.4%<br />

Table 4.4: Spot, Future <strong>an</strong>d Roll Return Time Series for Crude Oil<br />

rolling his position forward. The so-called roll return first introduced in Figure 4.8<br />

is mathematically derived in Theorem 4.1:<br />

Theorem 4.1 Roll Return<br />

Let F (t, T ) denote the commodity futures price at time t ∈ [0, T ] <strong>an</strong>d let P (t) be the<br />

commodity spot price at time t ∈ [0, T ]. Moreover, we have 0 ≤ s < t ≤ T . Then<br />

the roll return is given by:<br />

Proof:<br />

( ) ( )<br />

F (t, T ) P (t)<br />

rr(t) = ln<br />

− ln<br />

F (s, T ) P (s)<br />

} {{ } } {{ }<br />

futures return spot return<br />

(4.1)<br />

Recall, the spot price, denoted by P (t), is approximated by the front<br />

month futures price, denoted by F (t, T ), i.e. we have: P (t) = F (t, T ). Therewith,<br />

we c<strong>an</strong> calculate:<br />

r F (t) ≡<br />

( ) F (t, T )<br />

ln<br />

F (s, T )<br />

= ln(F (t, T )) − ln (F (s, T )) + ln (P (s)) − ln (P (s))<br />

} {{ }<br />

=P (t)<br />

Rearr<strong>an</strong>ging yields to the result.<br />

( ) ( )<br />

P (t) P (t − 1)<br />

= ln + ln<br />

, 0 ≤ s < t ≤ T (4.2)<br />

P (s) F (s, T )<br />

} {{ } } {{ }<br />

spot return roll return<br />

As shown in Figure 3.2 the copper market is in backwardation, e.g. the negative<br />

slope of the term structure disembogues into a positive roll return what we will show<br />

in the following example. The price data of the respective futures contract are given<br />

in Table 4.5.<br />

Calculating the return series with the same methodology described for the crude oil<br />

✷<br />

91


4 Commodity Indices<br />

Copper (US dollar) J<strong>an</strong> 06 Feb 06 Mar 06 Apr 06 May 06 Jun 06 Jul 06<br />

30. Dec 2005 4,538 →4,489 ↓<br />

4,431 4,359 4,291 4,231 4,173<br />

31. J<strong>an</strong> 2006 4,912 →4,886 ↓<br />

4,853 4,815 4,768 4,721<br />

28. Feb 2006 4,881 →4,842 ↓<br />

4,812 4,778 4,742<br />

31. Mar 2006 5,440 →5,423 ↓<br />

5,400 5,375<br />

28. Apr 2006 7,118 →7,066 ↓<br />

7,008<br />

31. May 2006 8,001 →7,968 ↓<br />

30. Jun 2006 7,425<br />

Table 4.5: Construction of a Futures Return Series for Copper<br />

example we end up with the values given in Table 4.6. Recall, the futures return<br />

series is calculated by following the arrows <strong>an</strong>d the spot return series by following<br />

the bold letters. The ”backwarded” term structure produced a positive roll return<br />

amounting to 3.9% <strong>as</strong> shown in the l<strong>as</strong>t column of Table 4.6.<br />

Future Return Spot Return Difference = Roll Return<br />

J<strong>an</strong> 2006 9.0% 7.9% 1.1%<br />

Feb 2006 -0.1% -0.7% 0.5%<br />

Mar 2006 11.7% 10.8% 0.8%<br />

Apr 2006 27.2% 26.9% 0.3%<br />

May 2006 12.4% 11.7% 0.7%<br />

Jun 2006 -7.1% -7.5% 0.4%<br />

Total 53.0% 49.2% 3.9%<br />

Table 4.6: Spot, Future <strong>an</strong>d Roll Return Time Series for Copper<br />

The examples above have shown the impact of the term structure to the investors<br />

return. If a market is in cont<strong>an</strong>go the negative roll return will diminish the final<br />

return in spite of price incre<strong>as</strong>es yielding to positive spot returns. To push back<br />

the negative rolling impact in cont<strong>an</strong>goed markets, someone could think about extending<br />

the rolling periods. For inst<strong>an</strong>ce, if the investor of the crude oil example<br />

had avoided rolling forward the positions monthly, <strong>an</strong>d instead would have invested<br />

in J<strong>an</strong>uary 2006 directly into the July 2006 contract he would have realized a futures<br />

return of ln ( 68.94<br />

63.25)<br />

= 8.6% because the roll return would have decre<strong>as</strong>ed to<br />

ln ( 63.25<br />

57.98)<br />

= −8.7%. This conclusion is used by Merrill Lynch. In May 2006 they<br />

introduced the ML Oil Return <strong>an</strong>d Income Index that rolls forward its oil futures<br />

positions every third month. 104 Backtesting h<strong>as</strong> shown that in fact they could realize<br />

<strong>an</strong> excess return in comparison to one month rolling, long only oil futures indices<br />

104 See [Merrill Lynch 2006]. To be precise, Merrill Lynch employ a short option trading facility <strong>as</strong><br />

well to minimize the negative influence of cont<strong>an</strong>go to the roll return.<br />

92


4.4 Decomposition of Index Returns<br />

over the l<strong>as</strong>t 2 years. Given the current term structure <strong>as</strong> of July 2006 of NYMEX<br />

crude oil shown in Figure 4.9 this strategy is expected to work over the next nine<br />

months namely until April 2007 properly. From this point on, the market is expected<br />

to be in backwardation again yielding to positive roll returns. Implicating,<br />

monthly rolling will be more attractive again.<br />

Figure 4.9: Term Structure of NYMEX Crude Oil <strong>as</strong> per July 2006<br />

Generally, the big public commodity indices described in Section 4.2 roll every month<br />

over a five day period each with 20% of the total futures investment caused by<br />

liquidity re<strong>as</strong>ons. Trading volume is clustered around the front month contracts.<br />

For inst<strong>an</strong>ce, the most traded commodity futures contract worldwide, the NYMEX<br />

crude oil future, h<strong>as</strong> in July 2006 approximately 230.000 open interests in the contract<br />

maturing in August 2006 less th<strong>an</strong> half of this about 130.000 open interests in<br />

the contract maturing one month later namely in September 2006 <strong>an</strong>d the contract<br />

maturing one year later namely in July 2007 h<strong>as</strong> just 10.000 open interests. The<br />

example is supported by different issuer’s studies proofing that liquidity is clustered<br />

around the nearby contracts. For inst<strong>an</strong>ce, following [Merrill Lynch 2006] the second<br />

nearby futures contract h<strong>as</strong> only a trading volume of two thirds of the trading volume<br />

of the first month futures contract. Nevertheless, Deutsche B<strong>an</strong>k h<strong>as</strong> ch<strong>an</strong>ged<br />

its trading strategy. They implemented the so-called optimum yield rolling strategy.<br />

Depending on the shape of the forward curve, they roll the contracts forward into<br />

contracts that under liquidity requirements maximize the roll return.<br />

93


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

Investor’s attention is generally attracted by <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses that are on <strong>an</strong> upwards<br />

move. Legends like Jim Rogers have helped to establish commodities <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set<br />

cl<strong>as</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d to convince m<strong>an</strong>y investors that the only way for commodities is up. The<br />

economic boom of emerging market countries <strong>an</strong>d the long l<strong>as</strong>ting exp<strong>an</strong>sion of production<br />

capacities will push prices further over the next years. But investors first<br />

have to underst<strong>an</strong>d that there is not the ”average commodity”. Therefore, the first<br />

part of this section, i.e. Section 5.1, will concentrate on single commodity returns<br />

<strong>an</strong>d their interactions. Introductory, Section 5.1.1 shall give a first inside into their<br />

different risk <strong>an</strong>d return profiles. We will use the conclusions from Section 3 <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Section 4.4 to decompose excess returns, i.e. the pure commodity return, aiming<br />

to identify whether commodities offer a risk premium or not <strong>an</strong>d how much risk<br />

<strong>an</strong> investor h<strong>as</strong> to bear when investing into selected commodities. An interesting<br />

observation will be, that in contr<strong>as</strong>t to traditional <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses, the risk me<strong>as</strong>ure<br />

volatility goes up in bullish markets. Commodity price surges come in line with low<br />

inventories <strong>an</strong>d the fear of supply interruptions yields into nervous market movements.<br />

Although, the different types of commodities are influenced by their own specific<br />

risk factors, technological progress allows new substitution possibilities. So, commodities<br />

that are on the first view totaly different among each other, might be more<br />

<strong>an</strong>d more driven by the same risk factors <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d sources. But in which extent<br />

c<strong>an</strong> similar price movements be observed? Section 5.1.2 will show that only<br />

commodities of the same group show high overlapping among their price movement<br />

characteristics while combining different commodity groups will yield into bal<strong>an</strong>ced<br />

risk <strong>an</strong>d return profiles. Section 5.1.3 will finally give the mathematical expl<strong>an</strong>ation<br />

of diversification <strong>an</strong>d therewith will state, why commodity indices are suitable to<br />

get bal<strong>an</strong>ced commodity exposure.<br />

The second part of this section, i.e. Section 5.2, will further focus on the statistical<br />

properties of such a bal<strong>an</strong>ced commodity exposure’s return. While different<br />

research focused on the construction <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>alysis of artificial commodity indices<br />

including e.g. [Gorton Rouwenhorst 2004] <strong>an</strong>d [Erb Harvey 2006], little is done in<br />

<strong>an</strong>alyzing actual market indices, e.g. [Kat Oomen 2006]. We will close the gap by<br />

<strong>an</strong>alyzing the DJ-AIGCI total return index <strong>an</strong>d its pure commodity return components.<br />

105<br />

We will uncover roll returns <strong>an</strong>d show their impact on total returns in<br />

105 The switch from excess return in Section 5.1 to total return in the Section 5.2 is motivated <strong>as</strong><br />

follows: The first part of Section 5 concentrates on the characteristics of single commodity<br />

94


5.1 Characteristics of Single <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

Section 5.2.1 <strong>an</strong>d 5.2.2. Our findings in Section 5.2.3 st<strong>an</strong>d in contr<strong>as</strong>t to findings of<br />

[Gorton Rouwenhorst 2004] <strong>an</strong>d [PIMCO 2006]. While we report negative skewness,<br />

they published positive. We re<strong>as</strong>on this with two facts: First, they both construct<br />

artificial indices that are not investable <strong>an</strong>d second, they consider a period from<br />

1970 until 2005. Therewith, the value development considers the two major price<br />

surges over the l<strong>as</strong>t 100 years.<br />

To close this section, we will report two major time series characteristics: stationarity<br />

in Section 5.2.4 <strong>an</strong>d autocorrelation in Section 5.2.5. Our findings are in line with<br />

[Kat Oomen 2006]. They’ve already reported that the facility of autocorrelation in<br />

selected commodity returns, including among others corn, soybe<strong>an</strong>s, live cattle, oil<br />

<strong>an</strong>d gold, got lost in index returns. 106<br />

5.1 Characteristics of Single <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

As we introduced the different commodity types in Section 2.1 it became clear that<br />

the single members of the commodity market differ among each other. Nevertheless,<br />

we identified dependencies resulting from substitutions or production hierarchical<br />

structures. The question to <strong>an</strong>swer in this section is consequently, how these<br />

macroeconomic dependencies c<strong>an</strong> be seen in statistical characteristics of return series’<br />

calculable from futures price time series following Definition C.2 <strong>an</strong>d how the<br />

interaction of different commodities c<strong>an</strong> yield to diversification effects.<br />

For it, we first <strong>an</strong>alyze the risk <strong>an</strong>d return profile of different commodities in<br />

Section 5.1.1. Caused by the consumption good facility of commodities, different<br />

pattern to traditional <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses occur.<br />

Moreover, it will come up that broad<br />

indices <strong>as</strong> of Section 4.2 have the most attractive risk <strong>an</strong>d return profile in comparison<br />

to single <strong>an</strong>d group commodity indices. This might indicate diversification<br />

effects. The mathematical b<strong>as</strong>ic for diversification is imperfect correlation between<br />

different <strong>as</strong>sets. Therefore, we will <strong>an</strong>alyze possible co-movements of selected commodity<br />

returns in Section 5.1.2. Finally, we will collect all results in Section 5.1.3<br />

<strong>an</strong>d will come up with the conclusion that commodity investment is most attractive<br />

in products linked to broad commodity indices that are bal<strong>an</strong>ced weighted over the<br />

three commodity groups, e.g. like the DJ-AIGCI. Closing, we show that the energy<br />

returns <strong>an</strong>d their interactions among each other, i.e. we focus on the pure commodity return.<br />

The second part of Section 5 aims to show distributional behavior of commodity exposure’s<br />

return. Pure futures return c<strong>an</strong> be seen <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> overlay to a portfolio but if <strong>an</strong> investor actually<br />

w<strong>an</strong>ts to invest a part of his wealth into commodities, he h<strong>as</strong> to do so over the collateralized<br />

version <strong>as</strong> described in Section 4.4, i.e. he had to consider total returns.<br />

106 A detailed data description of our sample c<strong>an</strong> be found in Appendix A.<br />

95


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

market’s price movements have a huge impact to broad indices although they are<br />

bal<strong>an</strong>ced weighted.<br />

5.1.1 Risk <strong>an</strong>d Return Profile<br />

When it comes to fin<strong>an</strong>cial investing the first two regarded me<strong>as</strong>urements are risk <strong>an</strong>d<br />

return. When <strong>an</strong> investor puts his money into <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set he is interested in the profit<br />

he will earn, i.e. the expected return of the investment, <strong>an</strong>d the entered risk, e.g.<br />

me<strong>as</strong>ured by the volatility of the expected return. Recall, in Section 3 we identified<br />

the two drivers of commodity futures prices to be the spot price respectively the<br />

expectation of the future spot price <strong>an</strong>d a risk premium respectively a risk premium<br />

on inventories called convenience yield. Because our investment focus is long term<br />

orientated <strong>an</strong>d commodities are traded with futures having a maturity we have to<br />

roll over the investment by <strong>an</strong>d by. As we have seen in Section 4.4 the calculable<br />

excess return representing the pure commodity return c<strong>an</strong> be divided into the spot<br />

return, i.e. a return that is generated by the value ch<strong>an</strong>ge of a commodity, <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

roll return, i.e. a return that is generated by the ch<strong>an</strong>ge of risk premiums. At the<br />

end of the day expected future returns are b<strong>as</strong>ed on the experiences of the p<strong>as</strong>t.<br />

Therefore, this section shall give <strong>an</strong> empirical overview of the risk <strong>an</strong>d return profile<br />

of historical commodity returns.<br />

For it, we identified a small peer group including respectively a single commodity<br />

from each commodity group <strong>as</strong> of Figure 2.1, a sub index representing each commodity<br />

group <strong>an</strong>d the two market dominating broad indices, the DJ-AIGCI <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

GSCI.<br />

To examine the value development of the different commodity indices we use the<br />

<strong>an</strong>nualized sample me<strong>an</strong> for a small peer group. 107 Continuous returns are time additive<br />

108 <strong>an</strong>d so <strong>an</strong>nualized values are reached by linear scaling of the sample me<strong>an</strong><br />

by the average number of observations per year. Table 5.1 shows the results for the<br />

return components 109 of the different commodity indices of our small peer group.<br />

107 To be precise: Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.2 at<br />

times t ∈ {1, . . . , T }. The sample me<strong>an</strong> is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

¯r = 1 T<br />

T∑<br />

r t (5.1)<br />

t=1<br />

108 See Equation (C.5).<br />

109 The single return components were separated <strong>as</strong> described in Section 4.4. Excess <strong>an</strong>d spot return<br />

series are published by the index issuers <strong>an</strong>d the roll returns were calculated <strong>as</strong> of Theorem 4.1.<br />

96


5.1 Characteristics of Single <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

Excess Return Spot Return Roll Return<br />

G<strong>as</strong>oline 33.6% 29.3% 4.3%<br />

Natural G<strong>as</strong> -16.0% 26.5% -42.5%<br />

Nickel 35.5% 32.1% 3.4%<br />

Zinc 11.9% 20.5% -8.6%<br />

Gold 9.4% 14.2% -4.8%<br />

Corn -25.7% 1.7% -27.4%<br />

Le<strong>an</strong> Hogs -13.5% 6.6% -20.1%<br />

Sugar 7.5% 9.4% -1.9%<br />

Energy Index 25.5% 29.7% -4.3%<br />

Industrial Metals Index 17.7% 20.1% -2.4%<br />

Precious Metals Index 10.3% 14.5% -4.2%<br />

Agricultural Index -14.9% 3.3% -18.2%<br />

DJ-AIGCI 12.0% 19.9% -7.9%<br />

GSCI 15.3% 22.0% -6.7%<br />

Table 5.1: Return Components of different Commodity Indices (1998-2006)<br />

Over the 8 year period starting in August 1998 all commodities have produced on<br />

average a positive spot return. But because commodity investments include rolling<br />

futures positions forward we need to take the roll returns into consideration. All<br />

group <strong>an</strong>d broad indices including more th<strong>an</strong> one particip<strong>an</strong>t produced on average<br />

negative roll returns. Implicating, most commodities have been in cont<strong>an</strong>go. Hilary<br />

Till, co-founder of Premia Capital M<strong>an</strong>agement LLC, h<strong>as</strong> investigated into the<br />

source of steady commodity returns. In [Till 2000] she identified commodities with<br />

statistically signific<strong>an</strong>t returns <strong>as</strong> these, whose underlying commodity have difficult<br />

storage situations. For these commodities, either storage is impossible, prohibitively<br />

expensive, or producers decide, it is much cheaper to leave the commodity in the<br />

ground th<strong>an</strong> to store it. Her findings are in line with earlier research by [Kolb 1996]<br />

who examined 45 commodity futures contracts between 1982 <strong>an</strong>d 2004. Both mention<br />

soybe<strong>an</strong> meal, live cattle, live hogs, crude oil, g<strong>as</strong>oline <strong>an</strong>d copper to be difficult<br />

to store <strong>an</strong>d to have signific<strong>an</strong>t positive returns. Storage c<strong>an</strong> act <strong>as</strong> a buffer. If too<br />

little of a commodity is produced, one c<strong>an</strong> draw on storage <strong>an</strong>d price does not need<br />

to ration dem<strong>an</strong>d. But for commodities with a difficult storage situation, ”... price<br />

h<strong>as</strong> to do a lot (or all) of the work of equilibrating supply <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d ...”. 110<br />

[Kolb 1996] showed that the average geometric excess return of the difficult to store<br />

commodities w<strong>as</strong> 3.5% over the period of 1982 to 2004. In contr<strong>as</strong>t, the average<br />

geometric excess return of the not difficult to store commodities w<strong>as</strong> -4.3% over the<br />

same period.<br />

110 See [Till 2000].<br />

97


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

Morg<strong>an</strong> St<strong>an</strong>ley investigated into the relationship between excess returns <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

time a commodity spent in cont<strong>an</strong>go respectively in backwardation. In the presentation<br />

[N<strong>as</strong>h Shrayer 2004] they show findings regarding the existence of a weak linear<br />

relationship between the average <strong>an</strong>nualized return produced by a commodity <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the time it spend in backwardation. They examined 18 commodities over the period<br />

1983 to 2004 <strong>an</strong>d identified heating oil, live cattle, copper, crude oil <strong>an</strong>d g<strong>as</strong>oline <strong>as</strong><br />

commodities with positive return <strong>an</strong>d positive time the commodity spend on average<br />

in backwardation.<br />

Figure 5.1 shows the percentage time a commodity spend in backwardation plotted<br />

against the <strong>an</strong>nualized me<strong>an</strong> of its excess return <strong>as</strong> of Table 5.1. Indeed, we c<strong>an</strong> also<br />

identify a linear relationship between this two components.<br />

Figure 5.1: Relationship between Backwardation <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>nualized Return<br />

More recently, [Till Feldm<strong>an</strong> 2006] extended the framework originated in the work<br />

of [N<strong>as</strong>h Shrayer 2004]. They found that the power of backwardation to explain<br />

commodity futures return is indeed valid, but requires the investor to have a very<br />

long investment horizon when relying on this indicator. Specifically, they examined<br />

soybe<strong>an</strong>, corn <strong>an</strong>d wheat futures over the period of 1950 to 2004. They found<br />

that a contracts average level of backwardation only explains 25% of the variation<br />

in futures returns over one year time frames, 42% of variation over two year time<br />

frames, 63% of variation over five year time frames <strong>an</strong>d robust 77% of variation over<br />

eight year time frames.<br />

All these research aims to <strong>an</strong>swer the question whether commodities offer a signific<strong>an</strong>t<br />

risk premium or not. This depends on how futures prices deviate from expected<br />

future spot prices or equivalent on how high their convenience yield is. This is very<br />

different from equities. Since the main re<strong>as</strong>on to buy stocks is investment, for stocks<br />

98


5.1 Characteristics of Single <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

it is plausible that prices are set such that the expected return exceeds the interest<br />

rate <strong>an</strong>d is higher for more risky stocks. For commodity futures to offer a risk<br />

premium, we need hedging dem<strong>an</strong>d to pull futures prices away from the respective<br />

expected future spot price. For the identified difficult to store commodities there is<br />

plausible tendency for hedgers to be predomin<strong>an</strong>tly on the sell side. As a result, the<br />

expected futures return is more likely to be positive th<strong>an</strong> negative.<br />

In general, no uniform conclusion about signific<strong>an</strong>t excess returns c<strong>an</strong> be made.<br />

But we came to the conviction that commodity’s risk premium vary over time dependent<br />

on the current <strong>an</strong>d expected supply <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d situation. Moreover, the<br />

price of commodities <strong>an</strong>d therewith the realized returns move through cycles over<br />

time caused by commodity’s consumption good facility. In periods of scarcity <strong>an</strong>d<br />

high hedging dem<strong>an</strong>d with high risk premiums new supply will enter the market<br />

yielding, according to experience, into over supply periods with falling prices, low<br />

or negative risk premiums <strong>an</strong>d negative industry growth with falling supply. New<br />

dem<strong>an</strong>d thrusts are firstly buffered by inventories to a certain degree but yielding<br />

again, according to experience, in a new period of scarcity <strong>an</strong>d the circle starts <strong>an</strong>ew.<br />

The current price surge came in line with high price movements over short periods,<br />

such <strong>as</strong> recently seen in crude oil <strong>an</strong>d copper markets, for inst<strong>an</strong>ce. Therefore,<br />

commodities are often thought to be extremely volatile. Indeed, in response to<br />

weather related events, supply shocks, e.g. caused by news about existing reserves,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d speculative trading some commodity prices may exhibit large swings over short<br />

periods. First research regarding this phenomena goes back to the theory of storage.<br />

Following [Kaldor 1939] volatility is inversly related to the level of inventories. When<br />

there are little or no inventories to buffer supply <strong>an</strong>d dem<strong>an</strong>d disequilibriums, prices<br />

may rise dramatically. As a consequence, rising prices <strong>an</strong>d rising volatility come in<br />

line <strong>an</strong>d both are negatively correlated to the level of inventory.<br />

Today, there exists a v<strong>as</strong>t amount of literature what investigates the volatility of commodity<br />

futures. A statistical study performed by [Fama French 1987] on a number<br />

of commodity futures including metals, wood <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>imals shows that the vari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

of prices incre<strong>as</strong>es adversely to inventory levels. [Germ<strong>an</strong> Nguyen 2002] investigated<br />

worldwide soybe<strong>an</strong> inventories over a 10 year period <strong>an</strong>d showed that volatility c<strong>an</strong><br />

be written <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> exact inverse function of inventory. Regarding energy markets, the<br />

property is the same <strong>an</strong>d widely discussed in actuality: whenever there is a downward<br />

adjustment of the estimated oil reserves in the US or <strong>an</strong>other region, oil prices<br />

<strong>an</strong>d their volatility incre<strong>as</strong>e sharply.<br />

99


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

To investigate the variability of different commodity indices we calculate the <strong>an</strong>nualized<br />

sample st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation, the minimum <strong>an</strong>d the maximum of daily log<br />

returns separately for the respective excess return (ER), spot return (SP) <strong>an</strong>d roll<br />

return (RR). The <strong>an</strong>nualized sample st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation, denoted by ¯σ, is calculated<br />

<strong>as</strong> the root of the the <strong>an</strong>nualized sample vari<strong>an</strong>ce 111 <strong>an</strong>d gives <strong>an</strong> absolute me<strong>as</strong>ure<br />

of the variability of returns to either the negative or positive side of the me<strong>an</strong>. In<br />

Table 5.2 we represent our findings for the small peer group already known from<br />

Table 5.1.<br />

The first observation is that spot volatility explains the main part of excess return<br />

volatility.<br />

The dispersion of roll returns are generally quite small in comparison<br />

to spot volatility. To underst<strong>an</strong>d this we have to recover that the spot price of a<br />

commodity is approximated by the price of the first nearby futures contract. The roll<br />

return is made by rolling the investment from the first into the second month futures<br />

contract <strong>an</strong>d therefore, the difference between these two prices relative to the price<br />

of the first nearby futures contract, e.g. the spot price. This difference depends<br />

of the shape of the forward curve. As we have already seen in Section 5.1.1, the<br />

shape of the forward curve is <strong>an</strong> expression of the current <strong>an</strong>d expected supply <strong>an</strong>d<br />

dem<strong>an</strong>d equilibrium. The rolling periods of our sample are monthly <strong>an</strong>d therewith<br />

short term orientated. Caused by the small time difference between the first <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the second nearby futures contract, sudden extreme events will effect both prices<br />

<strong>an</strong>d rolling over the investment will create only small roll returns. The described<br />

phenomena c<strong>an</strong> be seen in the copper example of the previous section. Going back<br />

to Table 4.5 we see a huge sudden spot price surge during March <strong>an</strong>d April from<br />

5,440 US dollar per contract to 7,118 US dollar per contract. But the price of the<br />

second month contract w<strong>as</strong> influenced in the same way. From Table 4.6 we take<br />

a small roll return of 0.3% in this month. This observation goes in line with the<br />

Samuelson effect well known <strong>an</strong>d often <strong>an</strong>alyzed in commodity related research,<br />

e.g. [Samuelson 1965] <strong>an</strong>d [Anderson D<strong>an</strong>thine 1983]. The Samuelson effect is called<br />

the property of commodity price volatility to decre<strong>as</strong>e with incre<strong>as</strong>ing maturity. It<br />

111 To be more precise: Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.2<br />

at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T } <strong>an</strong>d ¯r be the sample me<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong> in Equation (5.1). The sample vari<strong>an</strong>ce is<br />

defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

¯σ 2 = 1 T∑<br />

(r t − ¯r) 2 (5.2)<br />

T − 1<br />

Annualized values are calculated by scaling linear with the average number of observations per<br />

year because continuous returns are time additive. The square root of the sample vari<strong>an</strong>ce:<br />

is called the sample st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation.<br />

t=1<br />

¯σ = √¯σ 2 (5.3)<br />

100


5.1 Characteristics of Single <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

Return Std. Deviation Minimum Maximum<br />

ER 38.2% -12.8% 11.2%<br />

G<strong>as</strong>oline SP 38.3% -12.8% 11.2%<br />

RR 5.4% -2.5 1.9<br />

ER 55.0% -16.7% 18.8%<br />

Natural G<strong>as</strong> SP 55.5% -16.7% 18.8%<br />

RR 7.3% -7.7% 2.0%<br />

ER 36.0% -18.3% 13.6%<br />

Nickel SP 35.5% -18.2% 12.4%<br />

RR 4.9% -4.7% 10.8%<br />

ER 23.3% -8.9% 8.9%<br />

Zinc SP 23.1% -9.0% 8.9%<br />

RR 2.0% -2.1% 4.1%<br />

ER 16.4% -7.6% 8.8%<br />

Gold SP 16.3% -7.6% 8.8%<br />

RR 1.1% -1.4% 1.4%<br />

ER 22.2% -5.3% 6.5%<br />

Corn SP 22.7% -5.3% 6.5%<br />

RR 4.3% -3.3% 3.0%<br />

ER 27.5% -7.4% 6.9%<br />

Le<strong>an</strong> Hogs SP 30.4% -12.2% 11.8%<br />

RR 11.3% -5.4% 7.9%<br />

ER 32.9% -9.3% 8.4%<br />

Sugar SP 33.3% -9.3% 8.4%<br />

RR 4.5% -2.5% 2.5%<br />

ER 33.3% -14.4% 8.0%<br />

Energy Index SP 33.3% -14.4% 8.0%<br />

RR 3.5% -3.7% 2.8%<br />

ER 19.5% -9.0% 7.6%<br />

Industrial Metals Index SP 19.1% -9.1% 7.6%<br />

RR 2.5% -2.3% 4.4%<br />

ER 16.3% -8.3% 8.5%<br />

Precious Metals Index SP 16.3% -8.2% 8.5%<br />

RR 1.2% -1.5% 1.5%<br />

ER 17.0% -10.5% 8.6%<br />

Agricultural Index SP 17.4% -12.5% 9.8%<br />

RR 4.3% -2.9% 5.0%<br />

ER 15.0% -4.3% 4.8%<br />

DJ-AIGCI SP 15.2% -4.3% 4.8%<br />

RR 1.9% -2.1% 0.8%<br />

ER 22.7% -9.2% 6.5%<br />

GSCI SP 22.7% -4.3% 4.8%<br />

RR 2.2% -2.3% 1.6%<br />

Table 5.2: Volatility Components of different Commodity Indices (1998-2006)<br />

is explained by the fact that the arrival of news (e.g. on inventories) will have <strong>an</strong><br />

immediate impact on short-term futures prices, while long-term contract prices tend<br />

to remain unch<strong>an</strong>ged since production adjustments are likely to take place before<br />

the contracts come to delivery at maturity.<br />

The second observation is regarding the dispersion of the different commodities.<br />

They differ not only among each other, but also among each commodity group <strong>as</strong><br />

the sub indices tell. Moreover, the <strong>an</strong>nualized st<strong>an</strong>dard deviations r<strong>an</strong>ge from <strong>as</strong><br />

much <strong>as</strong> 55.0% for natural g<strong>as</strong> to <strong>as</strong> low <strong>as</strong> 16.4% for gold. Therefore, general<br />

statements about the ”high volatility” implicating high risks for investors c<strong>an</strong>not<br />

be supported. [Kat Oomen 2006] examined the development of commodity return<br />

101


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

volatility during different periods of the business cycle over a period of 1965 to 2005<br />

<strong>an</strong>d conclude, that ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the dispersion level c<strong>an</strong> be observed. Especially oil’s<br />

<strong>an</strong>d oil product’s prices react differently in different business cycle periods. During<br />

recessions they tend to be high volatile <strong>an</strong>d at the beginning of <strong>an</strong> exp<strong>an</strong>sion ph<strong>as</strong>e<br />

their variability tend to decre<strong>as</strong>e. Moreover, they report that most commodities<br />

including i.e. oil <strong>an</strong>d oil products, silver, platinum, copper, soybe<strong>an</strong>s, cocoa <strong>an</strong>d<br />

corn tend to be more volatile when the forward curve is in backwardation. This<br />

is not surprising when interpreting backwardation <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> indication of scarcity that<br />

usually is followed by price surges <strong>an</strong>d <strong>as</strong> described above this is positively related<br />

to volatility incre<strong>as</strong>es. 112<br />

Third, sub indices exhibit in general smaller st<strong>an</strong>dard deviations <strong>as</strong> their particip<strong>an</strong>ts.<br />

This might be <strong>an</strong> indication for diversification effects <strong>an</strong>d our guess is underlined<br />

by the small st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation of the broad indices.<br />

5.1.2 Correlation<br />

Correlation 113 is the normalized covari<strong>an</strong>ce 114 of two variables <strong>an</strong>d me<strong>as</strong>ures their<br />

co-movements in a r<strong>an</strong>ge of plus to minus one. Strong positive correlation indicates<br />

that upward movements in one returns series tend to come in line with upward movements<br />

in the other, <strong>an</strong>d similarly, strong negative correlation indicate that downward<br />

movements of the two series tend to go together. To me<strong>as</strong>ure the strongness of the<br />

relation someone c<strong>an</strong> calculate the so-called correlation coefficients including Pearson’s,<br />

Kendall’s <strong>an</strong>d Spearm<strong>an</strong>’s. They identify links between two variables in a<br />

r<strong>an</strong>ge of plus to minus one. A positive value indicates a positive relationship <strong>an</strong>d<br />

vice versa, a negative value identifies a negative connection. Absolute higher values<br />

indicate stronger co-movements.<br />

Looking at historical correlations is aiming to <strong>an</strong>swer the question whether the considered<br />

investment universe is homogeneous or heterogeneous. Or, alternatively <strong>as</strong><br />

[Erb Harvey 2006] state, ”is the commodity market a collection of securities that<br />

behave in a similar way, or is the market a collection of dissimilar securities?” While<br />

introducing the different commodity types in Section 2.1 we already uncovered some<br />

dependence structures between the single commodities. In Appendix B more examples<br />

c<strong>an</strong> be found, including a strong connection between the row commodity <strong>an</strong>d<br />

its downstream products, e.g.<br />

oil <strong>an</strong>d heating oil in Appendix B.1 or the interdependencies<br />

in the soybe<strong>an</strong> complex in Appendix B.11. We saw a link between<br />

112 Compare Table 6.5.<br />

113 For the formal mathematical definition see Definition C.15.<br />

114 For the formal mathematical definition see Definition C.14.<br />

102


5.1 Characteristics of Single <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

macroeconomic influences <strong>an</strong>d commodities, e.g. gold in Section 2.1.2.1, the behavior<br />

of prices when commodities c<strong>an</strong> serve <strong>as</strong> a complement or substitute for each<br />

other, e.g oil <strong>an</strong>d natural g<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong>d finally, we saw adverse price movements in livestock<br />

markets when grains markets move in a respective way in Section 2.1.3.3.<br />

To investigate the co-movement of futures returns over the l<strong>as</strong>t years in detail we<br />

will <strong>an</strong>alyze Person’s <strong>an</strong>d Kendall’s correlation coefficient. The first one is generally<br />

the most well known <strong>an</strong>d most used one. Unfortunately, it is restricted to the<br />

discovery of linear relationships between variables <strong>an</strong>d therefore, situations with<br />

non-linear dependence structures keep covered. Nevertheless, to get a first idea of<br />

the interactions between commodity returns the Pearson correlation coefficient is<br />

helpful <strong>an</strong>d for sample returns calculated <strong>as</strong> follows:<br />

Definition 5.1 Pearson Correlation<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } <strong>an</strong>d {l 1 , . . . , l T } be two discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom samples of different returns<br />

at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T } <strong>an</strong>d ¯r respectively ¯l be the sample me<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong> of Equation 5.1.<br />

The sample Pearson correlation coefficient is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

ρ =<br />

√<br />

1<br />

T −1<br />

∑<br />

1 T<br />

T −1 t=1 (r t − ¯r)(l t − ¯l)<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 (r t − ¯r) 2 √<br />

1<br />

T −1<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 (l t − ¯l) 2 (5.4)<br />

Our findings regarding the spot <strong>an</strong>d the roll returns are documented in Table 5.3. 115<br />

A correlation matrix is always symmetric because it makes no difference whether to<br />

take the correlation between e.g. nickel <strong>an</strong>d zinc price movements or zinc <strong>an</strong>d nickel<br />

price movements. If two commodity prices move statistically independent then a<br />

good estimate of their correlation should be insignific<strong>an</strong>tly different from zero highlighted<br />

with a brown color in Table 5.3.<br />

Examining our findings we realize higher similar price co-movements among commodity<br />

groups th<strong>an</strong> between them. But still, the price movements of commodities<br />

among a group are imperfectly correlated <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> investor c<strong>an</strong> improve investment<br />

characteristics by spreading his wealth by investing in sub instead of single commodity<br />

indices. Figure 5.2 illustrates the phenomena in the risk return space. The<br />

115 Yellow values are signific<strong>an</strong>t at the 1% alpha level, blue values are signific<strong>an</strong>t at the 5% alpha<br />

level <strong>an</strong>d brown values are insignific<strong>an</strong>t. We tested the null hypothesis of zero correlation <strong>an</strong>d<br />

used the t-test with the following test statistic:<br />

t =<br />

ρ<br />

√<br />

1 − ρ<br />

2 ∗ √ T − 2 (5.5)<br />

It follows a Student’s t-distribution with T − 2 degrees of freedom. For further details of<br />

hypothesis testing see Section 5.2.3, [Bamberg Baur 2002] or [K<strong>an</strong>ji 1999].<br />

103


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

Table 5.3: Pearson Correlation (1998-2006)<br />

commodity group indices are denoted by a circle <strong>an</strong>d some of its constituents by a<br />

quadrat or rect<strong>an</strong>gle. The dependence of the single commodities to the respective<br />

sub index is highlighted with a black oval.<br />

Figure 5.2: Diversification between single commodity groups<br />

Someone realizes that the investment in sub indices is more attractive th<strong>an</strong> in single<br />

commodities. Caused by the imperfect correlation between commodity group members,<br />

strong price movements of one commodity are bal<strong>an</strong>ced by moderate price<br />

104


5.1 Characteristics of Single <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

movements of <strong>an</strong>other. Implicating, the volatility of the whole group decre<strong>as</strong>es <strong>an</strong>d<br />

<strong>an</strong> investment that may not produce more revenues is still more attractive because<br />

of its lower risk structure.<br />

However, Definition 5.1 uncovers the problem with the Pearson correlation. Only<br />

the first two moments of a distribution are involved to me<strong>as</strong>ure the degree of dependence.<br />

Only the normal distribution family is wholly explainable with its first two<br />

moments. Thus, two variables could have zero correlation <strong>an</strong>d still be related over<br />

higher moments. Therefore, we take Kendall’s correlation coefficient also known <strong>as</strong><br />

Kendall’s tau additionally into consideration. It me<strong>as</strong>ures the degree of <strong>an</strong> arbitrary<br />

monotone relationship between two variables without <strong>an</strong>y <strong>as</strong>sumptions such<br />

<strong>as</strong> linearity or distribution. Moreover, it is robust against outliers.<br />

To calculate Kendall’s tau for two return series with observations at the same dates,<br />

the value of each observed return per index denoted with r t respectively l t is tacked<br />

with its r<strong>an</strong>k relative to the other return observations in the sample, i.e.<br />

with<br />

1, 2, . . . T . Now all values come from the uniform distribution of numbers 1, 2, . . . T .<br />

If all r t respectively l t have different values, each number is found exactly one time.<br />

If some observations of r t respectively l t have the same value, they get <strong>an</strong> average<br />

r<strong>an</strong>k. In either c<strong>as</strong>e, ( the sum ) of all <strong>as</strong>signed r<strong>an</strong>ks is equal to the sum of numbers<br />

1, 2, . . . T namely . Kendall’s tau uses the relative order of the r<strong>an</strong>ks to<br />

1<br />

2T (T +1)<br />

identify correlations: the r<strong>an</strong>k is higher, lower or equal if the values are higher, lower<br />

of equal. Therefore, it checks for all t = 1, . . . , T whether<br />

1. a pair is concord<strong>an</strong>t at time t, i.e. r t > r t+1 <strong>an</strong>d l t > l t+1 <strong>an</strong>d the number of<br />

concord<strong>an</strong>t states over the whole period is denoted with n c<br />

2. a pair is discord<strong>an</strong>t at time t, i.e. r t < r t+1 <strong>an</strong>d l t < l t+1 <strong>an</strong>d the number of<br />

discord<strong>an</strong>t states over the whole period is denoted with n d<br />

3. there is a tied observation, i.e. r t = r t+1 <strong>an</strong>d l t = l t+1 <strong>an</strong>d the number of<br />

tied r-observations is denoted by n tr <strong>an</strong>d the number of tied l-observations is<br />

denoted by n tl<br />

Definition 5.2 Kendall’s Correlation<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } <strong>an</strong>d {l 1 , . . . , l T } be two discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom samples of different returns<br />

at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T } <strong>an</strong>d recall the definitions of concord<strong>an</strong>t, discord<strong>an</strong>t ( <strong>an</strong>d tied )<br />

observations above. The total number of possible pairings of r t <strong>an</strong>d l t is T (T −1)<br />

.<br />

If there are no tied observation the Kendall correlation coefficient is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

2<br />

τ =<br />

n c − n d<br />

T (T − 1)/2<br />

(5.6)<br />

105


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

If there are tied observation the Kendall correlation coefficient is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

τ =<br />

√ (<br />

T (T −1)<br />

2<br />

− ∑ n tr<br />

i=1<br />

n tr,i (n tr,i −1)<br />

2<br />

n c − n d<br />

) (<br />

T (T −1)<br />

2<br />

− ∑ n tl<br />

i=1<br />

) (5.7)<br />

n tl,i (n tl,i −1)<br />

2<br />

Our findings are documented in Figure 5.4. 116 As someone c<strong>an</strong> see, Kendall’s tau is<br />

also st<strong>an</strong>dardized to a r<strong>an</strong>ge minus to plus one.<br />

Table 5.4: Kendall Correlation (1998-2006)<br />

Table 5.3 <strong>an</strong>d Table 5.4 <strong>an</strong>d show the respective correlation coefficients for the two<br />

sources of excess return, i.e. for the spot return (SP) <strong>an</strong>d the roll return (RR). We<br />

have already seen in Section 5.1.1 that the main part of investor’s return is driven by<br />

the spot price movements <strong>an</strong>d therefore, it explains the main part of co-movements<br />

between different commodities. 117<br />

Confirming statements in literature including<br />

116 Yellow values are signific<strong>an</strong>t at the 1% alpha level, blue values are signific<strong>an</strong>t at the 5% alpha<br />

level <strong>an</strong>d brown values are insignific<strong>an</strong>t. We tested the null hypothesis of zero correlation <strong>an</strong>d<br />

used the Kendall r<strong>an</strong>k correlation test with the following test statistic:<br />

t =<br />

τ<br />

√<br />

T (T − 1)(2T + 5)/18<br />

(5.8)<br />

It follows a st<strong>an</strong>dard normal distribution. For further details of hypothesis testing see<br />

Section 5.2.3, [Bamberg Baur 2002] or [K<strong>an</strong>ji 1999].<br />

117 Indeed, the correlations among the excess returns do not differ relev<strong>an</strong>tly from the correlations<br />

among the spot returns. To avoid redund<strong>an</strong>ce, they are not explicitly reported.<br />

106


5.1 Characteristics of Single <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

[Kat Oomen 2006a] <strong>an</strong>d [Erb Harvey 2006], there exists a high dependence within<br />

commodity groups, e.g. between g<strong>as</strong>oline <strong>an</strong>d natural g<strong>as</strong> or between nickel <strong>an</strong>d<br />

zinc, but a small dependency between the groups what is confirmed by the small<br />

correlation coefficients not only between the single commodities of different groups<br />

but also between the different group commodity indices. Especially agricultural<br />

products exhibit price movements that are not in line with price movements of the<br />

other commodity groups. To visualize this phenomena we plotted in Figure 5.3 in<br />

the left diagram the return observations of nickel against the return observations of<br />

zinc <strong>an</strong>d in the right diagram the return observations of the industrial metals index<br />

against the observations of the agricultural index. The red line gives <strong>an</strong> idea of how<br />

100% correlation of two variables would look like.<br />

Figure 5.3: Linear Correlation within <strong>an</strong>d between Commodity Groups (1998-2006)<br />

Comparing Pearson’s <strong>an</strong>d Kendall’s correlation coefficient we realize partly high differences.<br />

Especially the high linear correlations over 0.2 including the correlation<br />

between g<strong>as</strong>oline <strong>an</strong>d natural g<strong>as</strong>, nickel <strong>an</strong>d zinc <strong>an</strong>d industrial <strong>an</strong>d precious metals<br />

are only half that high in Kendall’s scale indicating that the first two moments are<br />

not enough to describe the relationship between commodity price movements.<br />

In fin<strong>an</strong>cial markets, the existence of non-linear dependence structures between returns<br />

is well known <strong>an</strong>d implicating the fact, that correlations may not be <strong>an</strong> appropriate<br />

me<strong>as</strong>ure of co-dependence. Nevertheless, correlation is related to the slope<br />

parameter of a linear regression model.<br />

107


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

Definition 5.3 Linear Regression Model<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } <strong>an</strong>d {l 1 , . . . , l T } be two discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom samples of different returns<br />

at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T }, α <strong>an</strong>d β two const<strong>an</strong>t inR <strong>an</strong>d ε t be <strong>an</strong> error term of identical<br />

<strong>an</strong>d independent distributed r<strong>an</strong>dom variables with me<strong>an</strong> zero <strong>an</strong>d vari<strong>an</strong>ce σε. 2 Let<br />

r t denote the dependent variable <strong>an</strong>d the l t the independent. A linear regression<br />

model is given by the equation of a line:<br />

r t = α + βl t + ε t (5.9)<br />

To fit such line through actual observed values we need <strong>an</strong> estimated line, denoted<br />

by ˆr t = ˆα + ˆβˆl t where ˆα <strong>an</strong>d ˆβ denote the estimate of the line intercept α <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

slope β. The residuals are defined <strong>as</strong> e t = r t − ˆr t . Then, the actual data points are<br />

the fitted model plus the residuals: r t = ˆα + ˆβl t + e t .<br />

It is logical to choose a method of estimating these parameters that in some way<br />

minimizes the residuals, since then the predicted values of the dependent variable<br />

will be closer to the observed values. Choosing estimates to minimize the sum of<br />

the residuals will not work, because large positive residuals would c<strong>an</strong>cel out large<br />

negative residuals. The sum of the absolute residuals could be minimized, but the<br />

mathematical properties of the estimators are much nicer if we minimize the sum of<br />

the squared residuals. This is called the ordinary le<strong>as</strong>t squares (OLS) criteria.<br />

Theorem 5.1 Estimates for the Linear Regression Model<br />

The ordinary le<strong>as</strong>t squares estimates for the linear regression model of Definition 5.3<br />

ˆα <strong>an</strong>d ˆβ are given by:<br />

ˆβ =<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 (r t − ¯r)(l t − ¯l)<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 (r t − ¯r) 2 (5.10)<br />

or ˆβ = 0 if r t = ¯r ∀t ∈ {1, . . . , T } <strong>an</strong>d<br />

ˆα = ¯r − ˆb¯l (5.11)<br />

Whereby ¯r <strong>an</strong>d ¯l denote the sample me<strong>an</strong>s <strong>as</strong> of Equation (5.1).<br />

Proof: Following the idea of OLS estimation we need to minimize the sum of<br />

squared residuals, i.e. the following equation:<br />

L(ˆα, ˆβ) =<br />

T∑<br />

[r t − (ˆα + ˆβl t )] 2<br />

t=1<br />

To find <strong>an</strong> optimum we need to set the first derivation regarding ˆα <strong>an</strong>d ˆβ zero <strong>an</strong>d<br />

108


5.1 Characteristics of Single <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

solving for the respective unknown.<br />

∂<br />

∂ ˆα L(ˆα, ˆβ) =<br />

=<br />

∂<br />

∂ ˆβ L(ˆα, ˆβ) =<br />

=<br />

T∑<br />

−2r t + 2(ˆα + ˆβl t )<br />

t=1<br />

T∑<br />

−r t + nˆα + ˆβ<br />

t=1<br />

T∑<br />

l t ≡ 0 (5.12)<br />

t=1<br />

T∑<br />

−2r t l t + 2(ˆα + ˆβl t )l t<br />

t=1<br />

T∑<br />

−r t l t + ˆα<br />

t=1<br />

t=1 t=1<br />

T∑<br />

l t + ˆβ<br />

T∑<br />

lt 2 ≡ 0 (5.13)<br />

With (5.12) = (5.13) there exists a unique solution given in 5.10 if <strong>an</strong>d only if not<br />

all values of l t are equal. Putting the solutions into the respective second partial<br />

derivations shows that the solutions yield indeed to a minimum. 118<br />

✷<br />

Comparing Equation 5.10 <strong>an</strong>d Equation 5.4 someone c<strong>an</strong> see the connection between<br />

the correlation coefficient <strong>an</strong>d the slope parameter of linear regression model:<br />

ˆβ =<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 (r t − ¯r)(l t − ¯l)<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 (r t − ¯r) 2<br />

=<br />

=<br />

∑<br />

1 T<br />

T −1 t=1 (r t − ¯r)(l t − ¯l)<br />

∑<br />

1 T<br />

T −1 t=1 (r t − ¯r) 2<br />

√<br />

1<br />

T −1<br />

√<br />

= ρ ∗ √<br />

∑<br />

1 T<br />

T −1 t=1 (r t − ¯r)(l t − ¯l)<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 (r t − ¯r) 2 √<br />

1<br />

T −1<br />

1<br />

T −1<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 (l t − ¯l) 2<br />

1<br />

T −1<br />

√<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 (l t − ¯l)<br />

∗ √<br />

2<br />

1<br />

T −1<br />

1<br />

T −1<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 (l t − ¯l) 2<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 (r t − ¯r) 2<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 (r t − ¯r) 2 (5.14)<br />

This concept is well known in equity markets <strong>an</strong>d used in the Capital <strong>Asset</strong> Pricing<br />

Model (CAPM) to me<strong>as</strong>ure the variability of stock returns in dependence of the<br />

variability of the market index. Figure 5.4 shall give a visual impression of the dependency<br />

of the GSCI <strong>as</strong> market index to the energy market. 119<br />

118 For further details see [Bamberg Baur 2002]<br />

119 The goodness of fit parameter R 2 T<br />

t=1<br />

= P (ˆrt−¯r)2<br />

T = 0.93 <strong>an</strong>d therewith relatively high. The<br />

t=1 (rt−¯r)2<br />

beta coefficient is signific<strong>an</strong>t at the 1% alpha level. For <strong>an</strong> introduction of signific<strong>an</strong>ce tests<br />

regarding regression coefficients see e.g. [Bamberg Baur 2002].<br />

109


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

Figure 5.4: Dependence of Market Index (1998-2006)<br />

It became clear how high the GSCI returns depend on returns of the energy market.<br />

This is not <strong>as</strong>tonishing because recall Figure 4.7 that uncovers the high overweighting<br />

of the GSCI in favor of energy products.<br />

Summing up, the above results show that the commodity market is not a homogeneous<br />

but a heterogeneous universe. As Section 2.1 let us already guess the markets<br />

consists of dissimilar <strong>as</strong>sets that depend on their own price influencing factors.<br />

Therefore, spreading its wealth among more th<strong>an</strong> one commodity c<strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>e investors<br />

perform<strong>an</strong>ce. Especially the low correlation between the different commodity<br />

groups is attractive <strong>an</strong>d provides diversification benefits.<br />

5.1.3 Diversification<br />

As [Campbell 2000] stats, m<strong>an</strong>y economists pronounce that ”there is no such thing<br />

<strong>as</strong> a free lunch”, but fin<strong>an</strong>ce theory does offer a free lunch: the reduction in risk<br />

that is obtainable through diversification. An investor who spreads his wealth among<br />

different investments c<strong>an</strong> reduce the volatility of his portfolio, provided only that the<br />

underlying investments are imperfectly correlated. Because this h<strong>as</strong> no impact on<br />

the return of a portfolio, there is ”no bill for a lunch”. Still, m<strong>an</strong>y investors ignore<br />

diversification possibilities <strong>an</strong>d are overinvested in favor of selected <strong>as</strong>set such <strong>as</strong> the<br />

stocks of their own country instead of diversifying internationally. They might feel<br />

110


5.1 Characteristics of Single <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

that the volatility reduction is small: ”the free lich is so meagre that it is nor even<br />

worth lining up at the buffet table”.<br />

The mathematical expl<strong>an</strong>ation for the phenomena diversification given in Theorem<br />

5.2 in comparison to the results from Section 5.1.2 highlight the subst<strong>an</strong>tial benefit:<br />

Theorem 5.2 Diversification<br />

Consider a portfolio with n equally weighted <strong>as</strong>sets <strong>an</strong>d denote its weights with<br />

x ∗ (n) = ( 1 n · · · 1<br />

n )T ∈ R n . Let C = (c ij ) i=1...n,j=1...n be the n × n symmetric covari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

matrix of the n <strong>as</strong>sets. Then the portfolio vari<strong>an</strong>ce σ 2 (x ∗ (n)) converges<br />

forn −→ ∞ against the average covari<strong>an</strong>ce ¯σ c ∈ R:<br />

σ 2 (x ∗ (n)) = ¯σ c + 1 n (¯σ2 − ¯σ c ) −→ ¯σ c for n −→ ∞ (5.15)<br />

Proof:<br />

th<strong>an</strong> defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

Let x define the <strong>as</strong>set weights of a portfolio. The portfolio vari<strong>an</strong>ce is<br />

σ 2 (x) = x T Cx<br />

n∑<br />

= x i x j c ij<br />

=<br />

i,j=1<br />

n∑<br />

x 2 i σi 2 +<br />

i=1<br />

n∑ n∑<br />

x i x j c ij<br />

i=1 j=1,i≠j<br />

Now put x = x ∗ (n) = ( 1 n · · · 1<br />

n )T ∈ R n <strong>an</strong>d it follows:<br />

σ 2 (x ∗ (n)) =<br />

=<br />

n∑<br />

n∑<br />

x ∗ i (n) 2 σi 2 +<br />

} {{ }<br />

i=1 1<br />

i=1<br />

n 2<br />

1<br />

( 1 n∑<br />

σi 2 )<br />

n n<br />

i=1<br />

} {{ }<br />

≡ ¯σ 2 average vari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

n∑<br />

j=1,i≠j<br />

x ∗ i (n) x ∗<br />

} {{ } }<br />

j(n)<br />

{{ }<br />

1 1<br />

n n<br />

+ n − 1<br />

n ( 1<br />

c ij<br />

n∑<br />

n∑<br />

c ij )<br />

n(n − 1)<br />

i=1 j=1,i≠j<br />

} {{ }<br />

≡ ¯σ c average covari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

lim n→∞<br />

= ¯σc + 1 n (¯σ2 − ¯σ n )<br />

} {{ }<br />

0<br />

= ¯σ c<br />

what is a const<strong>an</strong>t independent of n<br />

✷<br />

111


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

Recall, correlation is defined <strong>as</strong> the normalized covari<strong>an</strong>ce. Following, the Theorem<br />

shows that creating a portfolio of <strong>as</strong>sets that are imperfectly correlated among each<br />

other provides diversification because the portfolio vari<strong>an</strong>ce is bal<strong>an</strong>ced. The average<br />

covari<strong>an</strong>ce represents a lower bound, portfolio vari<strong>an</strong>ce goes against with incre<strong>as</strong>ing<br />

constituents.<br />

[Campbell 2000] examined the stock market to investigate the phenomena. He<br />

showed that individual stocks are getting more volatile over time but their correlation<br />

to other stocks is fallen. Therefore, <strong>an</strong> investor needs to avoid concentrated<br />

portfolios more th<strong>an</strong> ever <strong>an</strong>d identified around 25 to 30 stocks to be sufficient for<br />

optimal diversification. In commodity markets Deutsche B<strong>an</strong>k first investigated diversification<br />

effects in 2003. 120 They examined the 24 commodities of the GSCI <strong>an</strong>d<br />

found 5 constituencies to be sufficient for optimal diversification yielding into the<br />

composition of the DBLCI. Viewing Figure 5.5 we identify the DJ-AIGCI <strong>as</strong> the<br />

optimal investment vehicle to get broad diversified commodity exposure.<br />

Figure 5.5: Diversification among commodity groups<br />

An investor who needs to limit its downside <strong>as</strong> m<strong>an</strong>y institutional investors, is more<br />

attractive to get a low risk portfolio producing a predefined excess return over c<strong>as</strong>h<br />

return th<strong>an</strong> to maximize the upside. As we have already seen in Section 5.1.2<br />

diversification effects are higher between commodities of different commodity groups<br />

th<strong>an</strong> between commodities of the same group. In Figure 5.5 this is visualized through<br />

the left position of the broad diversified indices relative to the sub indices labeled<br />

again with a circle already known from Figure 5.2. In Section 4.2 we investigated<br />

the differences of the major commodity indices <strong>an</strong>d identified differences in their<br />

construction. They differ from the amount of constituents until their weights. Recall,<br />

120 See [Wilshire Research 2005].<br />

112


5.1 Characteristics of Single <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

in Figure 4.7 we summed up the weights of the single commodities <strong>an</strong>d sorted<br />

them into the buckets energy, industrials 121 <strong>an</strong>d agricultures to identify the degree<br />

of diversification among the three bid commodity groups. Independently of the<br />

weighting procedure or the number of constituencies of <strong>an</strong> index we realized <strong>an</strong><br />

over-weighting of the GSCI, the DBLCI <strong>an</strong>d the RICI to the energy sector <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong><br />

over-weighting of the CRB index to the agricultural sector. Only the DJ-AIGCI h<strong>as</strong><br />

a bal<strong>an</strong>ced distribution of its weights among the three commodity groups. Recalling,<br />

its weighting procedure is linked to world’s production of a commodity but also<br />

bounders the single weights to be higher th<strong>an</strong> 2% <strong>an</strong>d lower th<strong>an</strong> 33%. Examining<br />

Figure 5.5 we realize that this procedure pays off <strong>an</strong>d the index participates best<br />

from the different statistical properties of its single constituencies.<br />

Summing up, portfolio’s me<strong>an</strong> is the average of its underlying investment’s returns<br />

<strong>an</strong>d portfolio’s vari<strong>an</strong>ce is the average of its underlying covari<strong>an</strong>ces. This explains<br />

why it is better to invest in broad th<strong>an</strong> in single group commodity indices. With<br />

the exception of the agricultural group, we have seen that commodity groups are<br />

generally homogeneous yielding into low diversification benefits. Only the softs<br />

<strong>an</strong>d therewith the agricultural group behaves heterogenous among its constituencies.<br />

The disadv<strong>an</strong>tage of this group are lower returns <strong>an</strong>d high dependencies to<br />

unpredictable <strong>an</strong>d uncertain weather conditions. Broad indices bring the homogenous<br />

groups that are heterogenous among each other together yielding into strong<br />

diversification effects. But only if the index h<strong>as</strong> no excess weights in favor of one<br />

commodity group maximal diversification benefits c<strong>an</strong> be gathered.<br />

In Section 5.1.2 we have already seen that the energy group is domin<strong>an</strong>t not only<br />

in producing returns but also in having high correlations to all other commodities.<br />

This domin<strong>an</strong>ce together with the excess weights in favor to energy of the GSCI gave<br />

birth to very strong co-movements of the two return series’. As we have seen, the DJ-<br />

AIGCI does not have this excess weights but still, Table 5.3 <strong>an</strong>d Table 5.2 report<br />

high correlation between this return series’. To get a deeper inside into the risk<br />

factor structure underlying the returns of the different commodity groups included<br />

into the DJ-AIGCI we performed a so-called factor <strong>an</strong>alysis. The main purpose of<br />

the factor <strong>an</strong>alysis is to decompose a data matrix R consisting of different return<br />

time series into specific (U) <strong>an</strong>d common factors (F ). It is very similar to a more<br />

dimensional linear regression model. The difference is that in a regression model<br />

the regressors are explicitly given, in a factor model the regressors are implicitly<br />

extracted from the data matrix. The degrees, known <strong>as</strong> loadings, the common or<br />

specific factors influence the return series’ c<strong>an</strong> simult<strong>an</strong>eously be used to decompose<br />

121 This bucket includes metals but also commodities like rubber <strong>an</strong>d cotton.<br />

113


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

the correlation structure existing among the time series’.<br />

Therewith, identifying<br />

common risk factors <strong>an</strong>d their degree of influence comes in line with decomposing<br />

the underlying risk structure. Theorem 5.3 gives the mathematical formulation of<br />

the model.<br />

Theorem 5.3 Model of Factor Analysis<br />

Let (R) t=1,...,T ;j=1,...,n ∈ R (T ×n) be the data matrix which includes column-wise the<br />

discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom samples {r 1j , . . . , r T j } for j = 1, . . . , n different <strong>as</strong>sets at times<br />

t ∈ {1, . . . , T }. Denote with ¯r j , j = 1, . . . , n, the <strong>as</strong>sets’ specific sample me<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong><br />

of Equation (5.1) <strong>an</strong>d with ¯σ j , j = 1, . . . , n, the <strong>as</strong>sets’ specific sample st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

deviation <strong>as</strong> of Equation (5.3).<br />

Define the normalized variables z tj = r tj−¯r j<br />

¯σ j<br />

<strong>an</strong>d put them into the normalized data<br />

matrix (Z) t=1,...,T ;j=1,...,n ∈ R (T ×n) . Furthermore, define the matrix (F ) t=1,...,T ;l=1,...,k ∈<br />

R (T ×k) coding the normalized common factors <strong>an</strong>d put its weights a j,l with j =<br />

1, . . . , n <strong>an</strong>d l = 1, . . . , k into the matrix A ∈ R (n×k) . Additionally, define the matrix<br />

(U) t=1,...,T ;j=1,...,n coding the normalized specific factors <strong>an</strong>d put its weights d ij ≠ 0 if<br />

i ≠ j <strong>an</strong>d zero otherwise for i, j = 1, . . . , n into the matrix D ∈ R (n×n) .<br />

The Factor Analysis decomposes the st<strong>an</strong>dardized data matrix in the following form:<br />

Z = F A T + UD (5.16)<br />

Denote the correlation matrix with (P ) i=1,...,n;j=1,...,n ∈ R (n×n) including the Pearson<br />

correlation coefficients between the n <strong>as</strong>sets <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.15. With the representation<br />

of Z in Equation (5.16), the correlation matrix h<strong>as</strong> the following form:<br />

R = AA T + DD (5.17)<br />

Proof: Denote with I the identity matrix, i.e. a symmetric matrix with ones at<br />

the main diagonal <strong>an</strong>d zeros otherwise. With the notions of Theorem 5.3 the single<br />

elements of the st<strong>an</strong>dardized data matrix shall have the following representation for<br />

t = 1, . . . , T <strong>an</strong>d j = 1, . . . , n:<br />

z tj =<br />

k∑<br />

a jk F l + d j U ij<br />

l=1<br />

In matrix notion:<br />

Z = F A T + UD<br />

114


5.1 Characteristics of Single <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

We <strong>as</strong>sume that:<br />

the normalized specific factors are uncorrelated among each other, i.e.<br />

1<br />

n U T U = I (5.18)<br />

the normalized specific factors are uncorrelated to the normalized common factors,<br />

i.e.<br />

U T F = 0 (5.19)<br />

the normalized specific factors are uncorrelated among each other, i.e.<br />

With Definition C.15 follows:<br />

1<br />

n F T F = I (5.20)<br />

R = 1 n ZT Z<br />

(5.16)<br />

{}}{<br />

= (F A T + UD) T (F A T + UD)<br />

= F} {{ T F}<br />

AA T + (U} {{ T F}<br />

) T (A T D T ) T + U} {{ T F}<br />

A T D T + U} {{ T U}<br />

D T D<br />

}{{} = I<br />

(5.20)<br />

}{{} = 0<br />

(5.18)<br />

}{{} = 0<br />

(5.19)<br />

}{{} = I<br />

(5.18)<br />

= AA }{{}<br />

T + }{{} DD<br />

common normalized vari<strong>an</strong>ce specific normalized vari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

Statistical estimates are generated using, e.g. maximum likelihood methods. Further<br />

expl<strong>an</strong>ations are out of the scope at this point <strong>an</strong>d c<strong>an</strong> be found among others e.g.<br />

in [Bamberg Baur 2002].<br />

✷<br />

The visualization of our results are shown in Figure 5.6 where we plotted the common<br />

factor loadings that influence the respective return series <strong>an</strong>d therewith its<br />

normalized vari<strong>an</strong>ce most.<br />

We extracted three common risk factors implicitly from the data. The major challenge<br />

is the interpretation of these factors. In Figure 5.6 we see that the grains,<br />

agricultural, softs <strong>an</strong>d non-energy sub index stick out in one direction resulting in<br />

our conclusion that this might indicate a common risk factor symbolizing the agri-<br />

115


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

Figure 5.6: Factor Analysis (1991-2006)<br />

cultural risk. Furthermore, the precious metals, non-energy <strong>an</strong>d industrial metals<br />

sub index protrude in the same direction. We deduce that this indicates a common<br />

risk factor embodying the risk related to metal’s investments. Finally, the energy<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the DJ-AIGCI index show in the one direction no other sub index stick out to.<br />

We infer that energy is the l<strong>as</strong>t separate risk factor driving mainly the DJ-AIGCI<br />

returns, although the index h<strong>as</strong> no extra weight in favor to this commodity group.<br />

Therefore, the <strong>an</strong>alysis underlies the impact of the energy market to the whole commodity<br />

market.<br />

Summing up, this section h<strong>as</strong> shown that putting different commodities into a portfolio<br />

disembogues into diversification effects providing the investor with attractive<br />

risk <strong>an</strong>d return profiles. Nevertheless, the energy market h<strong>as</strong> the strongest influence<br />

to the whole commodity market in comparison to the metals <strong>an</strong>d agricultural<br />

markets. To show this, we used two different types of <strong>an</strong>alysis: <strong>an</strong> explicit <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong><br />

implicit one. Both produced the same result. Therefore, it is proofed how import<strong>an</strong>t<br />

broad diversified commodity exposure is <strong>an</strong>d that excess weights in favor of one<br />

commodity group c<strong>an</strong> cause unidirectional risk profiles.<br />

5.2 Properties of the DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

The l<strong>as</strong>t section h<strong>as</strong> shown that commodity investing c<strong>an</strong>not be seen <strong>as</strong> a homogenous<br />

one but is driven by different risk <strong>an</strong>d influencing factors. Finally, we deduced<br />

116


5.2 Properties of the DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

that broad diversified commodity indices represent the optimal vehicle to get commodity<br />

exposure. Diversification effects cause better risk <strong>an</strong>d return profiles in<br />

comparison to single commodity’s or commodity group’s. We identified the DJ-<br />

AIGCI <strong>as</strong> the index that weights are best bal<strong>an</strong>ced among the commodity groups<br />

under consideration.<br />

The following lines will introduce the specifications of this index’ returns. Starting,<br />

we will first give a brief overview of the perform<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d return characteristics in<br />

Section 5.2.1. Therefore, we divided the DJ-AIGCI total return into its elements <strong>as</strong><br />

of Figure 4.8 <strong>an</strong>d show the value <strong>an</strong>d risk propositions of the single elements. Recall<br />

from Section 4.4, the elements included interest rate, spot <strong>an</strong>d roll return. Second,<br />

we will <strong>an</strong>alyze the roll returns embodied in a DJ-AIGCI investment’s return in<br />

Section 5.2.2.<br />

The main purpose of <strong>an</strong>alyzing returns is to identify their distributional properties.<br />

This is needed to <strong>as</strong>sume their future behavior <strong>an</strong>d especially, their behavior in the<br />

portfolio context. Therefore, Section 5.2.3 will give a brief overview of this <strong>an</strong>alysis.<br />

A more <strong>an</strong>d more popular getting research field in statistics is time series <strong>an</strong>alysis<br />

<strong>an</strong>d b<strong>as</strong>ed on its results time series modeling of returns. Generally, these models are<br />

constructed <strong>as</strong> regression models which take historical values <strong>as</strong> regressor. To do so,<br />

someone needs two major characteristics, stationarity <strong>an</strong>d autocorrelation. The first<br />

one examines the ch<strong>an</strong>ge of the distribution characteristics over time. Our findings<br />

are presented in Section 5.2.4. Autocorrelation investigates the linear dependence of<br />

returns following on each other. This <strong>an</strong>alysis is reported in Section 5.2.5.<br />

5.2.1 Key Statistics<br />

The DJ-AIGCI w<strong>as</strong> introduced at 01.01.1991 with a starting value of 100. 122 The<br />

DJ-AIGCI m<strong>an</strong>ual [DJAIGCI 2006] gives inside into the calculation methodology<br />

that is in line with our expl<strong>an</strong>ations in Section 5.1.1 about the construction of a<br />

commodity index. As already mentioned in Section 4.2 the DJ-AIGCI is available<br />

for investment in two different types, the excess <strong>an</strong>d the total return index, <strong>an</strong>d it<br />

is additionally calculated <strong>as</strong> spot return. Therewith, it is possible to <strong>an</strong>alyze the<br />

single return elements of the index <strong>as</strong> of Figure 4.8. The calculation followed the<br />

simple scheme: first, we calculated the log returns of the time series published in<br />

Bloomberg. Subtracting the excess from the total return identified the interest rate<br />

component <strong>an</strong>d subtracting the spot from the excess return identified the roll return<br />

122 From this point on we use data series starting at 01.01.1991 to cover the whole history of the<br />

index.<br />

117


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

component. To show the development of the single elements <strong>an</strong>d its value proposition<br />

we calculated price series following Definition C.3 <strong>an</strong>d plotted the results in<br />

Figure 5.7.<br />

Figure 5.7: Perform<strong>an</strong>ce of DJ-AIGCI Components<br />

Comparing the price series it becomes clear that although commodity spot prices<br />

have performed extraordinary over the l<strong>as</strong>t years, <strong>an</strong> investor could not participate<br />

fully because he had to bear the negative roll returns caused by shifting the investment<br />

forward over time, i.e. rolling futures contracts. But if <strong>an</strong> investor had<br />

gone into the collateralized version of the index, he would have been better off. The<br />

interest rate return w<strong>as</strong> that high that it over compensated the negative roll returns<br />

<strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> investor could have picked up the extraordinary spot return development of<br />

the l<strong>as</strong>t years. The question to <strong>an</strong>swer is, which type of return either total or excess<br />

h<strong>as</strong> to be considered when it comes to commodity investment. If <strong>an</strong> investor w<strong>an</strong>ts<br />

to get commodity exposure <strong>as</strong> actual part of his portfolio, he needs to consider the<br />

total return. He takes a certain amount of his wealth <strong>an</strong>d directly invests it. Because<br />

this is not possible in futures contracts, he puts the money <strong>as</strong> collateral to his<br />

futures engagement in a risk free interest earning instrument. Recall, this is done<br />

by all mutual funds tracking a certain commodity index. The other alternative is,<br />

that <strong>an</strong> investor w<strong>an</strong>ts to deal with the leverage effect, futures investments provide<br />

by the minimal c<strong>as</strong>h requirements only used to serve possible margin calls. Then he<br />

h<strong>as</strong> to consider the excess return <strong>as</strong> the actual pure commodity return. Following<br />

Theorem 4.1 <strong>an</strong>d because of the publishing of the DJ-AIGCI spot return index it is<br />

quite e<strong>as</strong>y to divide the excess return into its elements: excess, spot <strong>an</strong>d roll return<br />

<strong>as</strong> shown in Figure 5.8.<br />

118


5.2 Properties of the DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

Figure 5.8: Return Behavior of DJ-AIGCI Components<br />

As mentioned in [DJAIGCI 2006], rolling takes place monthly around the eighths<br />

business day. The futures are rolled forward in 20% portions over a five day period.<br />

This procedure c<strong>an</strong> be observed in the resulting roll return series noticeable by<br />

clearly different from zero returns over the five day rolling period. Because roll<br />

returns are a se<strong>as</strong>onal phenomena once a month they show different patterns th<strong>an</strong><br />

the spot or excess returns <strong>as</strong> it c<strong>an</strong> be seen in Figure 5.8.<br />

Closing this section, the key figures of the commodity return elements are summarized<br />

in Table 5.5 <strong>an</strong>d the above mentioned became clearer in real values: although<br />

spot commodity prices produced on average <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>nual return of 6.84%, <strong>an</strong> investor<br />

realized only 54% of total namely 3.72% per <strong>an</strong>num. The additional 3.12% per <strong>an</strong>num<br />

were eaten up by negative roll returns. But taking DJ-AIGCI exposure over a<br />

collateralized investment would have produced on average 7.63% per <strong>an</strong>num.<br />

Total<br />

Return<br />

Excess<br />

Return<br />

Spot<br />

Return<br />

Roll<br />

Return<br />

Annualized arithmetic me<strong>an</strong> 7.63% 3.70% 6.62% -2,85%<br />

Total value gain 228.88% 78.03% 174,23% -35,85%<br />

Annualized st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation 12.66 12.66% 12.74% 1.71%<br />

Minimum (daily) -9.15% -9.17% -9.17% -0.58%<br />

Maximum (daily) 4.85% 4.82% 4.82% 2.16%<br />

Me<strong>an</strong> (daily) 0.03% 0.01% 0.03% -0.01%<br />

Medi<strong>an</strong> (daily) 0.04% 0.03% 0.04% 0.00%<br />

99% VaR -2.03% -2.04% -2.04% -0.41%<br />

95% VaR -1.24% -1.26% -1.26% -0.18%<br />

Table 5.5: Key Statistics of DJ-AIGCI Components<br />

The minimum <strong>an</strong>d maximum values show the total dispersion of the returns. In<br />

119


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

comparison to excess <strong>an</strong>d spot returns, roll returns are small. This c<strong>an</strong> also be<br />

seen in Figure 5.8 by comparing the scales 123 <strong>an</strong>d the huge difference in <strong>an</strong>nualized<br />

st<strong>an</strong>dard deviations underlies the statement. Because the me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d the st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

deviation are sensitive against outliers we calculated the medi<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d the Value at<br />

Risk (99% <strong>an</strong>d 95%). The medi<strong>an</strong> is defined <strong>as</strong> the middle value of a series, i.e.<br />

sorting the members of series <strong>as</strong>cending, the medi<strong>an</strong> is the value that lies in the<br />

middle so that 50% of the series’ members are smaller <strong>an</strong>d 50% are bigger th<strong>an</strong><br />

the medi<strong>an</strong>. Its formal definition is given in Definition C.17. The Value at Risk is<br />

actually the qu<strong>an</strong>tile of the return distribution <strong>as</strong> defined in Definition C.18. 124 The<br />

99% VaR this value that only 1% of the return series is smaller th<strong>an</strong> the 99% VaR<br />

<strong>an</strong>d 99% of the return series are bigger th<strong>an</strong> the 99% VaR. In the same way, the<br />

95% VaR is this value that only 5% of the return series are smaller th<strong>an</strong> the 95% VaR<br />

<strong>an</strong>d 95% of the return series are bigger th<strong>an</strong> the 95% VaR. Taking the minimum<br />

daily log return of -9.17% in comparison to the VaR values we realize that this w<strong>as</strong><br />

really <strong>an</strong> unusual outlier <strong>an</strong>d that in 99% of the days over the l<strong>as</strong>t 15 years the<br />

negative returns didn’t fall below -2.04%.<br />

5.2.2 Roll Returns<br />

As we have seen in the previous section roll returns are a major re<strong>as</strong>on why investors<br />

couldn’t participate wholly on the commodity price surge of the l<strong>as</strong>t years.<br />

Figure 5.9 shows the negative perform<strong>an</strong>ce of the DJ-AIGCI roll return in larger<br />

scale th<strong>an</strong> in Figure 5.7. In this large scale the rolling periods c<strong>an</strong> better be seen<br />

<strong>an</strong>d we clearly observe that roll returns follow a jump process caused by their se<strong>as</strong>onal<br />

occurrence monthly.<br />

Negative roll returns come in line with a time when the majority of the underlying<br />

commodities are in cont<strong>an</strong>go <strong>an</strong>d positive roll returns occur when the majority of the<br />

underlying commodities are in backwardation. Figure 5.9 shows that longer periods<br />

of backwardation are followed by longer periods of cont<strong>an</strong>go <strong>an</strong>d that the negative<br />

returns in cont<strong>an</strong>go periods are higher th<strong>an</strong> the positive returns in backwardation<br />

periods. This explains the wavelike downwards move of the perform<strong>an</strong>ce line. At<br />

the moment discussions are coming up that speculate about a synthetic created<br />

cont<strong>an</strong>go caused by a similar rolling procedure of the major commodity indices. To<br />

investigate this problem we show in Figure 5.10 the percent of time the DJ-AIGCI<br />

123 Because the minimum return of -9.17% occurred <strong>as</strong> a st<strong>an</strong>d alone outlier at the inception of the<br />

DJ-AIGCI, we cut of the value for better observability of the general return development.<br />

124 For a detailed discussion of the VaR see [Zagst 2002].<br />

120


5.2 Properties of the DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

Figure 5.9: Perform<strong>an</strong>ce of DJ-AIGCI Roll Returns<br />

spent in cont<strong>an</strong>go versus the time it spend in backwardation. Indeed, there is a<br />

small trend that the time of cont<strong>an</strong>go is incre<strong>as</strong>ing. But this is not a phenomena<br />

created during the l<strong>as</strong>t years it seems to be a steady process of 4% growth over a<br />

five year period.<br />

Figure 5.10: Time the DJ-AIGCI spent in Cont<strong>an</strong>go or in Backwardation<br />

Matt Schwab, a m<strong>an</strong>aging director in the investor coverage group at AIG Fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

Products, mentioned in <strong>an</strong> interview, the people who are involved in the creation <strong>an</strong>d<br />

mainten<strong>an</strong>ce of the DJ-AIGCI are aware of the fact that commodities spent historically<br />

more time in cont<strong>an</strong>go th<strong>an</strong> in backwardation. Moreover, ”when institutions<br />

<strong>as</strong>k me if p<strong>as</strong>sive flows are causing the cont<strong>an</strong>go <strong>an</strong>d hurting index perform<strong>an</strong>ce,<br />

we highlight the fact that at the end of 2005, p<strong>as</strong>sive money w<strong>as</strong> just 3% of the<br />

size of the overall over-the-counter commodity derivatives market.” 125 In contr<strong>as</strong>t to<br />

125 See [Risknet 2006].<br />

121


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

Deutsche B<strong>an</strong>k who ch<strong>an</strong>ged their rolling procedure into a dynamic optimum yield<br />

one, m<strong>an</strong>y investors are not interested in these kind of trading strategy. John Brynjolfsson,<br />

head of the Pimco Real Return Commodity Strategy Fund 126 stated in <strong>an</strong><br />

interview: ”Aside from missing the liquidity that is present in the front-end month,<br />

having <strong>an</strong> index that c<strong>an</strong> make or lose money by extending to different calendars is<br />

a relatively speculative process that certainly should not be part of a p<strong>as</strong>sive index<br />

definition strategy.” 127<br />

Because roll returns are zero during the non rolling periods <strong>an</strong>d this is the main time<br />

during a month, the zero return is the domin<strong>an</strong>t one <strong>as</strong> shown in the left diagram<br />

of Figure 5.11.<br />

Figure 5.11: Distribution Ch<strong>an</strong>ge<br />

We plotted on the left side a histogram 128 of the real roll returns <strong>an</strong>d on the right<br />

side we plotted the pure roll returns, i.e. the roll return that actually occurred during<br />

the rolling periods. Of the original 3902 daily observations, only 908 data points<br />

are left taking only the pure roll returns into consideration. This h<strong>as</strong> the adv<strong>an</strong>tage<br />

that we c<strong>an</strong> separately <strong>an</strong>alyze the cont<strong>an</strong>go <strong>an</strong>d the backwardation times of the<br />

market, i.e. how are positive <strong>an</strong>d negative roll returns distributed. As the right<br />

diagram in Figure 5.11 clearly shows negative returns occurred historically more often<br />

th<strong>an</strong> positive ones, i.e. the bars on the negative side of the diagram are higher<br />

th<strong>an</strong> the bars on the positive side. But high irregular outliers c<strong>an</strong> be found more<br />

126 Recall, the fund w<strong>as</strong> introduced in Section 4.3 <strong>an</strong>d is by far the biggest commodity mutual fund<br />

on the market. It tracks the DJ-AIGCI.<br />

127 See [Risknet 2006].<br />

128 Further details about the contraction of a histogram see Section 5.2.3.<br />

122


5.2 Properties of the DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

often on the positive side of the distribution, i.e. the distribution h<strong>as</strong> a long right tail.<br />

Finally, Table 5.6 shows the key statistics for both, the actual <strong>an</strong>d the pure roll<br />

returns.<br />

Roll Return<br />

Pure Roll Return<br />

Annualized arithmetic me<strong>an</strong> -2.85% -2.85%<br />

Total value gain -35.85% -35.85%<br />

Annualized st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation 1.71% 1.68%<br />

Minimum (daily) -0.58% -0.58%<br />

Maximum (daily) 2.16% 2.16%<br />

Me<strong>an</strong> (daily) -0.01% -0.05%<br />

Medi<strong>an</strong> (daily) 0.00% -0.04%<br />

99% VaR -0.41% -0.48%<br />

95% VaR -0.18% -0.40%<br />

Table 5.6: Key Statistics of DJ-AIGCI Roll Return<br />

It c<strong>an</strong> clearly be seen that me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d medi<strong>an</strong> are negative in pure roll returns what<br />

additionally underlies the statement that commodities where historically more often<br />

in cont<strong>an</strong>go th<strong>an</strong> in backwardation. Because the data population decre<strong>as</strong>ed, the<br />

VaR values have more expl<strong>an</strong>atory power <strong>an</strong>d are not bi<strong>as</strong>ed to zero.<br />

In the following section we will switch between the actual <strong>an</strong>d the real pure returns<br />

depending on the <strong>an</strong>alysis. It makes no sense to investigate in Section 5.2.3 the<br />

distribution of the actual roll returns because <strong>as</strong> it c<strong>an</strong> be seen in the left diagram<br />

of Figure 5.11 the distribution is too much bi<strong>as</strong>ed to zero. But on the other h<strong>an</strong>d,<br />

it makes no sense to <strong>an</strong>alyze pure roll returns in Section 5.2.4 <strong>an</strong>d 5.2.5 from the<br />

time series point of view.<br />

5.2.3 Distribution<br />

To study commodity returns <strong>an</strong>d their effects to other <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses, it is best to<br />

study their distributional properties, i.e. we w<strong>an</strong>t to underst<strong>an</strong>d the behavior of<br />

historical returns across <strong>as</strong>sets to implicate later, how we c<strong>an</strong> model their distribution<br />

129 for forec<strong>as</strong>ting <strong>an</strong>d/or portfolio allocation purposes. Because this <strong>an</strong>alysis<br />

aims to <strong>an</strong>alyze a real commodity investment in the portfolio allocation space, total<br />

returns are considered.<br />

129 For a general introduction or review of statistical distribution <strong>an</strong>d their moments see <strong>an</strong>y introductory<br />

statistics or time series <strong>an</strong>alysis book, e.g. [Bamberg Baur 2002] or [Tsay 2002].<br />

123


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

All major theories in fin<strong>an</strong>ce are b<strong>as</strong>ed on the <strong>as</strong>sumption of normal distributed<br />

log returns respectively the multivariate normal distribution of multiple <strong>as</strong>sets in<br />

a portfolio. Therefore, it is import<strong>an</strong>t to examine whether the data sample under<br />

consideration satisfies the <strong>as</strong>sumption of normality or not. A first introduction to<br />

the distribution gives a so-called histogram that shows the frequency a single return<br />

occurs. Because commodity log returns are real numbers infinite m<strong>an</strong>y values c<strong>an</strong><br />

occur. 130 Therefore, in dependence of the dispersion of the data small buckets are<br />

defined <strong>an</strong>d every historical return is put into one <strong>an</strong>d the number of returns in the<br />

bucket are counted <strong>an</strong>d printed <strong>as</strong> bars. 131<br />

Figure 5.12 shows the histograms for the DJ-AIGCI total return <strong>an</strong>d for the pure<br />

commodity return components, the spot <strong>an</strong>d the roll return, for the period 1991-2006.<br />

Additionally a plot of a normal distribution with the sample me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d sample st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

deviation is plotted for better comparability.<br />

Figure 5.12: Histogram with Norm-Fit of DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

Unfortunately, viewing the data in this way already tells that the historically occurred<br />

log returns did not follow a perfect normal distribution. Especially, the roll<br />

returns are far away of being normal distributed. However, to get a deeper inside<br />

into the distribution properties of the returns we need to examine their defining<br />

moments. We have already introduced the sample me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d the sample vari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

of a return series. But the first two moments uniquely just determine the normal<br />

distribution. To check whether the data sample under consideration satisfies the<br />

130 For a brief introduction to number theory see [Broecker 1995]<br />

131 To be more precise: Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ [1, T ]<br />

<strong>an</strong>d ¯r be the sample me<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong> in Equation (5.1). Given the origin ¯r <strong>an</strong>d a bin width h, then<br />

the bins of the histogram are defined <strong>as</strong> the intervals [¯r + mh, ¯r + (m + 1)h] for m ∈ Z. The<br />

density estimator ˆf in a histogram is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

ˆf(r) = 1<br />

T h (no. of r i in the same bin <strong>as</strong> r) (5.21)<br />

124


5.2 Properties of the DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

<strong>as</strong>sumption of normality or not, <strong>as</strong> a first indicator we need to investigate the symmetry<br />

<strong>an</strong>d tail behavior of the sample. The two characteristics are described by the<br />

third centered <strong>an</strong>d with respect to the second moment, i.e. the st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation,<br />

normalized moment called skewness <strong>an</strong>d the fourth centered <strong>an</strong>d with respect to the<br />

second moment, i.e. the st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation, normalized moment called kurtosis.<br />

The conventional sample coefficients are given by: 132<br />

Definition 5.4 Sample Skewness<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T }.<br />

Denote with ¯r the sample me<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong> of Equation (5.1) <strong>an</strong>d with ¯σ the sample st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

deviation <strong>as</strong> of Equation (5.3). The sample skewness is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

¯S =<br />

T<br />

(T − 1)(T − 2)<br />

T∑<br />

( ) 3 rt − ¯r<br />

(5.22)<br />

t=1<br />

¯σ<br />

Skewness is a me<strong>as</strong>ure of the symmetry of the probability distribution of a realvalued<br />

r<strong>an</strong>dom variable. Roughly speaking, a distribution h<strong>as</strong> positive skew or is<br />

right-skewed if the right tail, i.e. the tail with the higher returns, is longer <strong>an</strong>d negative<br />

skew or is left-skewed if the left tail, i.e. the tail with the lower returns, is longer.<br />

Definition 5.5 Sample Kurtosis<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T }.<br />

Denote with ¯r the sample me<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong> of Equation (5.1) <strong>an</strong>d with ¯σ the sample st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

deviation <strong>as</strong> of Equation (5.3). The sample kurtosis is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

¯K =<br />

T (T + 1)<br />

(T − 1)(T − 2)(T − 3)<br />

T∑<br />

( ) 4 rt − ¯r 3(T − 1)2<br />

−<br />

¯σ (T − 2)(T − 3)<br />

t=1<br />

(5.23)<br />

Kurtosis is a me<strong>as</strong>ure of the ”peakedness” <strong>an</strong>d the tail behavior of the probability<br />

distribution of a real-valued r<strong>an</strong>dom variable. Higher kurtosis me<strong>an</strong>s the vari<strong>an</strong>ce is<br />

influenced by infrequent extreme deviations. For a st<strong>an</strong>dard normal distribution the<br />

skewness is zero <strong>an</strong>d the kurtosis is three. Therefore, the definition of the kurtosis<br />

is mainly given relative to the st<strong>an</strong>dard normal distribution, i.e. adjusted by three<br />

132 The given sample estimators are adjusted to be unbi<strong>as</strong>ed <strong>an</strong>d used in m<strong>an</strong>y statistical programs.<br />

For further details of their derivation see [Groeneveld Meeden 1984] or [Bamberg Baur 2002].<br />

125


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

<strong>as</strong> in Definition 5.5.<br />

Unfortunately, both me<strong>as</strong>ures are not robust against outliers because both, the<br />

me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d the st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation are influenced by them. [Kim White 2004] study<br />

different alternatives <strong>an</strong>d we decided to introduce a robust skewness me<strong>as</strong>ure first<br />

mentioned in [Bowley 1920] b<strong>as</strong>ed on qu<strong>an</strong>tiles. The α% - qu<strong>an</strong>tile value q α is chosen<br />

that α% of all realized returns in the sample are smaller th<strong>an</strong> the α% - qu<strong>an</strong>tile value<br />

q α . 133<br />

Definition 5.6 Bowley Skewness<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T } <strong>an</strong>d<br />

let q α be <strong>as</strong> defined in C.18 with α ∈ [0, 1]. The Bowley skewness is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

¯ S B = q 0.75 + q 0.25 − 2q 0.5<br />

q 0.75 − q 0.25<br />

(5.24)<br />

It c<strong>an</strong> e<strong>as</strong>ily be seen that for a symmetric distribution the Bowley skewness is zero.<br />

Both values, the sample <strong>an</strong>d the Bowley skewness for the different types of the DJ-<br />

AIGCI return components are documented in Table 5.7. The robust estimation of<br />

Bowley is much closer to zero. Implicating, the return distribution is influenced by<br />

extreme events.<br />

Total Return Spot Return Pure Roll Return<br />

Me<strong>an</strong> 0.03% 0.03% -0.05%<br />

Medi<strong>an</strong> 0.04% 0.04% -0.04%<br />

St<strong>an</strong>dard deviation 0.08% 0.81% 0.22%<br />

Sample Skewness -0.32 -0.31 1.81<br />

Bowley Skewness -0.03 -0.05 -0.32<br />

Sample Kurtosis 5.98 5.83 13.08<br />

Moors Kurtosis 0.12 0.10 0.55<br />

Table 5.7: Distribution Statistics of DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

[Moors 1988] showed that the conventional me<strong>as</strong>ure of kurtosis ¯K c<strong>an</strong> be interpreted<br />

<strong>as</strong> a me<strong>as</strong>ure of dispersion of a distribution around the two values µ ± σ. 134 Hence,<br />

¯K c<strong>an</strong> be large when probability m<strong>as</strong>s is concentrated either near the me<strong>an</strong> µ or in<br />

the tails of the distribution. B<strong>as</strong>ed on this interpretation he proposed the following<br />

robust kurtosis me<strong>as</strong>ure:<br />

133 The formal definition c<strong>an</strong> be found in C.18.<br />

134 The formal definitions of µ <strong>an</strong>d σ c<strong>an</strong> be found in C.10 <strong>an</strong>d C.11.<br />

126


5.2 Properties of the DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

Definition 5.7 Moors Kurtosis<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T } <strong>an</strong>d<br />

let q α be <strong>as</strong> defined in C.18 with α ∈ [0, 1]. The Moors kurtosis is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

K¯<br />

M = (q 0.875 − q 0.625 ) + (q 0.375 − q 0.125 )<br />

− 1.23 (5.25)<br />

q 0.75 − q 0.25<br />

Moors created this estimator b<strong>as</strong>ed on the idea that the two terms, (q 0.875 − q 0.625 )<br />

<strong>an</strong>d (q 0.375 − q 0.125 ), are large respectively small if relatively small respectively high<br />

probability m<strong>as</strong>s is concentrated in the neighborhood of q 0.75 <strong>an</strong>d q 0.25 corresponding<br />

to large respectively small dispersion around the two values µ + σ <strong>an</strong>d µ − σ. The<br />

denominator is a scaling factor, ensuring that the statistic is invari<strong>an</strong>t under linear<br />

tr<strong>an</strong>sformation. It is e<strong>as</strong>y to calculate that the Moors kurtosis h<strong>as</strong> the value 1.23<br />

for a st<strong>an</strong>dard normal distribution. 135 For comparability, Definition 5.7 gives the<br />

adjusted value relative to the normal distribution.<br />

Both values, the sample <strong>an</strong>d the Moors kurtosis for the different types of the<br />

DJ-AIGCI return components are documented in Table 5.7. On the first view it<br />

might be surprising that both values fall much apart from each other. But recall<br />

the difference in the definitions. The sample kurtosis me<strong>as</strong>ures both, the peakedness<br />

around the me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d fat tails. In contr<strong>as</strong>t, the Moors kurtosis just me<strong>as</strong>ures the<br />

dispersion around µ ± σ. Viewing again the histograms in Figure 5.12 uncovers<br />

that indeed the dispersion around µ ± σ is quite modest but the peak around the<br />

me<strong>an</strong> is very high. This explains why the two values fall much apart from each other.<br />

Summing up, the return distributions of the DJ-AIGCI components seem to be different<br />

from the normal distribution. To check whether our observations are r<strong>an</strong>domly<br />

for our special sample or whether we c<strong>an</strong> generalize the statement of non-normality<br />

to different observations, we performed some hypothesis tests for normality. The<br />

major idea of hypothesis testing is to compare distribution’s characteristics of a<br />

sample with the distribution’s characteristics of a reference distribution, in our c<strong>as</strong>e,<br />

to compare the sample distribution of DJ-AIGCI log returns with the normal distribution.<br />

How does it work in practise? First we formulate the null hypothesis of normality<br />

that we will test against the alternative of non normality, aiming to reject the null<br />

hypothesis with a m<strong>an</strong>ageable alpha error to reach signific<strong>an</strong>t statements, i.e. to<br />

make sure that the observation is not r<strong>an</strong>domly for the specific data sample but<br />

135 q 0.875 = −q 0.125 = −1.15, q 0.25 = −q 0.75 = −0.68, q 0.375 = −q 0.125 = −0.32<br />

127


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

c<strong>an</strong> be generalized. Second, we choose a normal distribution facility <strong>an</strong>d derive a<br />

me<strong>as</strong>ure function called test statistic that compares the value of the sample facility<br />

with the value of the normal distribution facility. Third, we judge b<strong>as</strong>ed on the outcome<br />

of the test statistic whether to reject the null hypothesis or not. Over time,<br />

different test statistics b<strong>as</strong>ed on different facilities were derived. We will present<br />

the three mainly used ones, the Lilliefors Kolmogorov-Smirnov, the Shapiro <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

Jaque-Bera Test.<br />

The Lilliefors Test is <strong>an</strong> adaption of the Kolmogorov-Smirnov Test. It is named<br />

after Hubert Lilliefors, professor of statistics at George W<strong>as</strong>hington <strong>University</strong> but<br />

actually the test w<strong>as</strong> developed independently by Lilliefors <strong>an</strong>d by V<strong>an</strong> Soest. The<br />

b<strong>as</strong>ic idea behind the test is the same <strong>as</strong> the idea behind the Kolmogorov-Smirnov<br />

Test of finding the biggest dist<strong>an</strong>ce between the empirical <strong>an</strong>d reference cumulative<br />

probability density function of a sample observation:<br />

Definition 5.8 Lilliefors Kolmogorov Smirnov Test<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T }.<br />

The total number of observation be T . Let ¯r denote the sample me<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong> defined in<br />

Equation (5.1), ¯σ 2 denote the sample vari<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>as</strong> defined in Equation (5.21) <strong>an</strong>d<br />

¯σ = √¯σ 2 be the sample st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation <strong>as</strong> of Equation (5.3). Moreover, define<br />

the tr<strong>an</strong>sformation of the sample observations Z t = rt−¯r , count in F ¯σ<br />

t the number of<br />

sample observations that are smaller or equal to Z t <strong>an</strong>d define the sample probability<br />

<strong>as</strong>: L(Z t ) = Ft<br />

T<br />

normality <strong>as</strong>: N (Z t ) = ∫ Z t<br />

−∞<br />

. Finally, define the probability under the <strong>as</strong>sumption of st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

√1<br />

2π<br />

e (− 1 2 x2 )dx . The Lilliefors Test Statistic is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

L = max{|L(Z t ) − N (Z t )|, |L(Z t ) − N (Z t−1 )|} (5.26)<br />

t<br />

So L me<strong>as</strong>ures the absolute value of the biggest difference between the probability<br />

<strong>as</strong>sociated to Z t when Z t is normally distributed, <strong>an</strong>d the empirical probability of<br />

Z t , e.g. the frequencies actually observed. Because the empirical distribution is<br />

discrete, the term |L(Z t ) − N (Z t−1 )| is needed to cover that the maximum absolute<br />

difference c<strong>an</strong> occur at either endpoints of the empirical distribution.<br />

For different alpha errors the critical values c<strong>an</strong> be found in amongst others, e.g.<br />

[Lilliefors 1967], [V<strong>an</strong> Soest 1967] <strong>an</strong>d [Molin Abdi 1998]. The outcome of the test<br />

for our sample data of DJ-AIGCI excess returns c<strong>an</strong> be found in Table 5.8.<br />

The next test brings us back in the world of regression introduced in Section 5.1.2.<br />

128


5.2 Properties of the DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

The idea is to obtain a test statistic for normality by dividing the square of <strong>an</strong><br />

appropriate linear combination of the sample order statistic by the usual estimator<br />

of the sample vari<strong>an</strong>ce:<br />

Definition 5.9 Shapiro Test<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T }.<br />

The Shapiro Test statistic tests the null hypothesis that the sample {r 1 , . . . , r T } comes<br />

from a normal distribution. First, create the order statistic r (1) , . . . , r (T ) <strong>as</strong> in C.21.<br />

m<br />

Second, define (a 1 , . . . , a T ) = T V −1<br />

with m = (m m T V −1 V −1 m 1, . . . , m T ) T denoting the<br />

expectations of <strong>an</strong> order statistic of <strong>an</strong> i.i.d. sample from the st<strong>an</strong>dard normal distribution<br />

<strong>an</strong>d V is the covari<strong>an</strong>ce matrix of those order statistic. The Shapiro Test<br />

statistic is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

W = (∑ T<br />

i=1 a ir (i) ) 2<br />

( ∑ T<br />

i=1 (r i − ¯r) 2 (5.27)<br />

The b<strong>as</strong>ic idea of the test is to think about a regression between <strong>an</strong> order statistic of<br />

the observation sample <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> order statistic of a sample generated from the st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

normal distribution: Let x (1) , x (2) , . . . , x (T ) denote <strong>an</strong> ordered r<strong>an</strong>dom sample<br />

of size T from a st<strong>an</strong>dard normal distribution <strong>as</strong> defined in C.21 <strong>an</strong>d define with<br />

Definitions C.21, C.10 <strong>an</strong>d C.14 for i, j = 1, 2, . . . , T :<br />

E(x i ) = m i<br />

cov(x i , x j ) = v ij<br />

Let r (1) , . . . , r (T ) denote the order statistic of the sample <strong>as</strong> defined in C.21. The<br />

objective is to derive a test for the hypothesis that this is a sample from a normal<br />

distribution with unknown me<strong>an</strong> µ <strong>an</strong>d vari<strong>an</strong>ce σ 2 . If the r (i) are a normal sample<br />

then r (i) c<strong>an</strong> be expressed <strong>as</strong>:<br />

r (i) = µ + σx (i) (5.28)<br />

for i = 1, 2, . . . , T . Then, the derivation of W is b<strong>as</strong>ed on the Aitken’s generalized<br />

le<strong>as</strong>t squares estimation of regression coefficients 136 <strong>an</strong>d the results of Lloyd to<br />

derive le<strong>as</strong>t square estimates b<strong>as</strong>ed on order statistics. 137<br />

The test rejects the null<br />

hypothesis of normality if W is too small because the numerator of the statistic is<br />

the normalized le<strong>as</strong>t square regression coefficient of the regression between the order<br />

statistic of the observation sample <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> order statistic of a sample generated from<br />

the normal distribution <strong>an</strong>d the denominator of the statistic is the sample vari<strong>an</strong>ce.<br />

136 See [Aitken 1935] or [Powell 2006].<br />

137 See [Lloydes 1952].<br />

129


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

If the sample comes from a normal distribution both values should have the same<br />

value. Following ) Lemma 2 <strong>an</strong>d 3 in [Shapiro Wilk 1965] W is caped by 1 <strong>an</strong>d floored<br />

by .<br />

(<br />

T m 2<br />

1<br />

T −1<br />

Finally, the Jarque Bera Test uses a test statistic b<strong>as</strong>ed on skewness <strong>an</strong>d kurtosis to<br />

test for normality.<br />

Definition 5.10 Jarque Bera Test<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T } <strong>an</strong>d<br />

let ¯S <strong>an</strong>d ¯K be defined in Definition 5.4 <strong>an</strong>d Definition 5.5. The Jaque Bera Test<br />

statistic is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

JB =<br />

(T − k)<br />

6<br />

(<br />

¯S 2 + ( ¯K )<br />

− 3) 2<br />

4<br />

(5.29)<br />

k denotes the number of estimated coefficients that were needed to create the series.<br />

The Jaque Bera Test statistic h<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>ymptotic chi-squared distribution with two<br />

degrees of freedom.<br />

Since samples from a normal distribution have <strong>an</strong> expected<br />

skewness of 0 <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> expected kurtosis of 3, <strong>an</strong>y deviation from this incre<strong>as</strong>es the<br />

Jarque Bera test statistic what yield to finally with crossing the critical value to a<br />

rejection of the null hypothesis.<br />

Table 5.8 summarizes the empirical results for our data sample of DJ-AIGCI excess<br />

returns.<br />

Statistic p-Value Action<br />

Lilliefors Test 0.05 0.0% reject H 0<br />

Shapiro Test 0.97 0.0% reject H 0<br />

Jarque Bera Test 5853 0.0% reject H 0<br />

Table 5.8: Signific<strong>an</strong>ce Tests for Normality of DJ-AIGCI Total Return<br />

All tests reject the null hypothesis of normality. Implicating, we could not proof<br />

that historical log returns of the DJ-AIGCI components are normally distributed.<br />

However, we c<strong>an</strong> construct <strong>an</strong> empirical distribution, the so-called Kernel distribution<br />

<strong>as</strong> seen in Figure 5.13. The first step of viewing empirical data w<strong>as</strong> the construction<br />

of a histogram. Intuitively, the b<strong>as</strong>ic idea of getting more accurate estimates<br />

for the empirical distribution would be to make the bins smaller <strong>an</strong>d to define the<br />

130


5.2 Properties of the DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

empirical density function <strong>as</strong> the sum of the bins. Actually, this method is called the<br />

naive estimation of the density <strong>an</strong>d more accurate explained in [Silverm<strong>an</strong> 1992]. A<br />

more sophisticated idea is to define dumps around the observations <strong>an</strong>d to add them<br />

together <strong>as</strong> the empirical density function. This method is called kernel estimation<br />

<strong>an</strong>d defined <strong>as</strong> follows:<br />

Definition 5.11 Kernel Estimation<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T } <strong>an</strong>d<br />

let h define the window width, also called smoothing parameter or b<strong>an</strong>dwidth. The<br />

empirical density function is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

ˆf(r) = 1<br />

T h<br />

T∑<br />

( ) r − rt<br />

K<br />

h<br />

t=1<br />

(5.30)<br />

whereby the so-called kernel function satisfies:<br />

∫ ∞<br />

−∞<br />

K(r)dr = 1 (5.31)<br />

In statistical computation the smoothing parameter h = (4/3) 1/5 σT 1/5 derived in<br />

[Silverm<strong>an</strong> 1992] <strong>an</strong>d the Gaussi<strong>an</strong> kernel function<br />

K(r) = √ 1<br />

<br />

−<br />

e<br />

r2 2<br />

2π<br />

(5.32)<br />

because of its continuity <strong>an</strong>d differentiability properties became excepted <strong>an</strong>d therefore,<br />

we will use them, too. The result of this estimation technique are shown in<br />

Figure 5.13. Additionally, we plotted a normal distribution for comparability.<br />

Figure 5.13: Kernel Distribution with Norm-Fit of DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

Summing up, commodity returns exhibit negative skewness <strong>an</strong>d excess kurtosis when<br />

131


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

considering the traditional estimates <strong>as</strong> of Definition 5.4 <strong>an</strong>d <strong>as</strong> of Definition 5.5.<br />

Their against outliers robust estimators, the Bowley Skewness <strong>an</strong>d the Moors Kurtosis,<br />

have shown that the distribution is influenced by extreme events <strong>an</strong>d peaked<br />

around the me<strong>an</strong>. Considering the results of the robust estimators they are much<br />

nearer to the reference values for a normal distribution, i.e. cle<strong>an</strong>ing the data of<br />

outliers might result into returns that are nearly normally distributed. Nevertheless,<br />

using the original data sample all tests for normal distribution failed <strong>an</strong>d finally, the<br />

construction of <strong>an</strong> empirical density showed visually that indeed commodity returns<br />

are not normally distributed.<br />

5.2.4 Stationarity<br />

In time series <strong>an</strong>alysis the first step is to investigate stationarity, i.e. ch<strong>an</strong>ges of<br />

the distribution characteristics over time. As we already known, the first interesting<br />

characteristic is the location parameter me<strong>an</strong>. Taking again a look at Figure 5.7 we<br />

observe ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the me<strong>an</strong> of the DJ-AIGCI price series, i.e. there are incre<strong>as</strong>ing<br />

<strong>an</strong>d decre<strong>as</strong>ing periods. But viewing again Figure 5.8 namely the time series of the<br />

log returns we realize that they seem to shake around a const<strong>an</strong>t me<strong>an</strong>. But being<br />

mathematically precise, stationarity is defined <strong>as</strong> follows.<br />

Definition 5.12 Strictly Stationarity<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T }. The<br />

time series r t is said to be strictly stationary if the joint distribution of (r t1 , . . . , r tk )<br />

is identical to that of (r t1 +t, . . . , r tk +t) for all t, where k is <strong>an</strong> arbitrary positive integer<br />

<strong>an</strong>d (t 1 , . . . , t k ) is a collection of k positive integers.<br />

In other words, strict stationarity requires that the joint distribution of (r t1 , . . . , r tk )<br />

is invari<strong>an</strong>t under time shifts. This is empirically hard to find <strong>an</strong>d therefore, a weaker<br />

form of stationarity shall help to h<strong>an</strong>dle small distribution ch<strong>an</strong>ges over time.<br />

Definition 5.13 Weakly Stationarity<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T }.<br />

The time series r t is said to be weakly stationary if the me<strong>an</strong> of r t <strong>an</strong>d the covari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

between r t <strong>an</strong>d r t+k is time invari<strong>an</strong>t for <strong>an</strong> arbitrary integer k.<br />

132


5.2 Properties of the DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

Weak stationarity exactly embodies what w<strong>as</strong> said introductory. It implies that the<br />

data fluctuate with const<strong>an</strong>t variation around a const<strong>an</strong>t level. To test for stationarity,<br />

different tests were established over time. Because we are already familiar<br />

with regressions <strong>an</strong>d the OLS estimation methodology from Section 5.1.2, we will<br />

introduce the Dickey Fuller Test that is b<strong>as</strong>ed on the same principles. For it, we<br />

first set up a simple autoregressive time series model:<br />

r t = βr t−1 + ε t (5.33)<br />

As in Definition 5.3 ε t is <strong>an</strong> error term of identical <strong>an</strong>d independent distributed r<strong>an</strong>dom<br />

variables with me<strong>an</strong> zero <strong>an</strong>d vari<strong>an</strong>ce σε. 2 Furthermore, <strong>as</strong>sume for simplicity<br />

that r 0 = 0 <strong>an</strong>d that ε t ’s come from a normal distribution. If β = 1 the time series<br />

model of (5.33) reduces to:<br />

r t = ε t + ε t−1 + . . . + ε 1 (5.34)<br />

This describes a r<strong>an</strong>dom walk with r t ∼ N (0, σεt), 2 i.e the r t ’s have a time dependent<br />

distribution in contradiction to Definition 5.13. Therefore, to proof the hypothesis of<br />

stationarity [Dickey Fuller 1979] suggested the null hypothesis of β = 1. Rejecting<br />

the null hypothesis implicates, that a series c<strong>an</strong> be seen <strong>as</strong> stationary, statistically<br />

signific<strong>an</strong>t.<br />

Definition 5.14 Dickey Fuller Test<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T }.<br />

With the derivation methodology <strong>as</strong> of the proof to Theorem 5.1, the OLS estimate<br />

for β in (5.33) is given <strong>as</strong>:<br />

ˆβ =<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 r t−1r t<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 r2 t−1<br />

(5.35)<br />

Furthermore, the usual OLS st<strong>an</strong>dard error for the estimation coefficient is given<br />

<strong>as</strong>:<br />

ˆσ 2ˆβ =<br />

=<br />

∑<br />

1 T<br />

T −1 t=1 (r t − ˆβr t−1 ) 2<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 r2 t−1<br />

ˆσ<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 r2 t−1<br />

(5.36)<br />

133


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

Then, the Dickey <strong>an</strong>d Fuller test statistic under the null hypothesis of β = 1 is<br />

defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

DF = ˆβ − 1<br />

ˆσ ˆβ<br />

(5.37)<br />

To decide whether to reject the test or not, we need to know the distribution of DF<br />

test statistic to identify the critical regions.<br />

Theorem 5.4 Distribution of the Dickey Fuller Test Statistic<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T }<br />

d<br />

<strong>an</strong>d let W (t) denote a Wiener process <strong>as</strong> of Definition xy. The symbol −→ denotes<br />

convergence in distribution <strong>as</strong> of Definition xy. With the notion of Definition 5.14<br />

<strong>an</strong>d T −→ ∞ it follows that the Dickey Fuller test statistic DF <strong>as</strong> of Definition 5.14<br />

is under the null hypothesis of β = 1 <strong>as</strong>ymptotically distributed <strong>as</strong>:<br />

DF<br />

d<br />

−→<br />

1<br />

(W 2 (1)2 − 1)<br />

( ∫ ) 1/2<br />

(5.38)<br />

1<br />

W (r)dr 0<br />

Proof: With the notion of Definition 5.14 <strong>an</strong>d under the null hypothesis of β = 1,<br />

it follows:<br />

DF = ˆβ − 1<br />

ˆσ ˆβ<br />

H 0 :β=1<br />

{}}{<br />

= ˆβ − β<br />

ˆσ ˆβ<br />

With (5.33) <strong>an</strong>d (5.35):<br />

DF =<br />

( P T<br />

)<br />

t=1 r t−1r t<br />

P T −<br />

t=1 r t−1<br />

ˆσ ˆβ<br />

( P T<br />

)<br />

t=1<br />

P (rt−εt)<br />

T<br />

t=1 r t−1<br />

Furthermore, taking (5.36) yields to:<br />

DF =<br />

( P T<br />

)<br />

t=1 r t−1ε t<br />

P T<br />

t=1 r2 t−1<br />

(<br />

) 1/2<br />

ˆσ<br />

P 2<br />

T<br />

t=1 r2 t−1<br />

134


5.2 Properties of the DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

Exp<strong>an</strong>ding with 1 = T : T<br />

DF =<br />

=<br />

=<br />

(<br />

1<br />

T<br />

P T<br />

t=1 r t−1ε t<br />

1<br />

T 2 P T<br />

t=1 r2 t−1<br />

(<br />

ˆσ 2 T 2<br />

P T<br />

t=1 r2 t−1<br />

)<br />

) 1/2<br />

(<br />

1<br />

∑ T<br />

T t=1 r t−1ε t<br />

∑<br />

1 T<br />

T 2 t=1 r2 t−1<br />

(<br />

1<br />

T<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 r t−1ε t<br />

)<br />

(<br />

ˆσ 2<br />

T 2 ∑ T<br />

t=1 r2 t−1<br />

)<br />

⎛<br />

)<br />

⎜<br />

∗ ⎝<br />

d<br />

−→<br />

1<br />

(<br />

ˆσ 2 T<br />

P 2<br />

T<br />

t=1 r2 t−1<br />

⎞<br />

⎟<br />

) 1/2<br />

⎠<br />

1<br />

(W 2 (1)2 − 1)<br />

( ∫ ) 1/2<br />

1<br />

W (r)dr 0<br />

The convergence follows with Proposition 9 in [Hamilton 1994] page 486. Its multilateral<br />

proof is out of the scope of this thesis.<br />

The respective values of DF for different critical values c<strong>an</strong> be found in amongst<br />

others [Hamilton 1994], for inst<strong>an</strong>ce.<br />

Our findings for the DJ-AIGCI total return <strong>an</strong>d its pure commodity return components<br />

c<strong>an</strong> be found in Table 5.9.<br />

Statistic p-Value Action<br />

Total Return -15.00 0.00% reject H 0<br />

Spot Return -15.23 0.00% reject H 0<br />

Roll Return -11.32 0.00% reject H 0<br />

Pure Roll Return -4.01 0.01% reject H 0<br />

Table 5.9: Dickey Fuller Test for Stationarity<br />

✷<br />

The test clearly shows that commodity returns c<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>sumed to be stationary.<br />

5.2.5 Autocorrelation<br />

In Section 5.1.2 we already introduced the me<strong>as</strong>ure for linear dependency of two<br />

variables, the correlation, <strong>an</strong>d Figure 5.3 visualized the degree of dependence. In<br />

this section we are interested in <strong>an</strong>alyzing the linear dependence between returns<br />

following each other. Therefore, the equivalent to Figure 5.3 is done in Figure 5.14.<br />

But there we didn’t plot two different sample realizations at the same time against<br />

each other, we plotted the realizations of the same sample at different points in time<br />

135


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

against each other. Plotting the sample against the time shifted sample is done<br />

with the so-called time lag. In Figure 5.14 the DJ-AIGCI total return <strong>an</strong>d its pure<br />

commodity return components are plotted until the fourth time lag. The diagonal<br />

line is plotted for better comparability <strong>an</strong>d represents 100% correlation.<br />

Figure 5.14: Lagged Plot of DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

We realize that both, total <strong>an</strong>d spot returns don’t show <strong>an</strong>y autocorrelation pattern,<br />

but roll returns do. The zero cross pattern occurs through the non rolling periods.<br />

After visual examining the data we need to check mathematically whether autocorrelation<br />

is signific<strong>an</strong>t or not. Therefore, we first define the so-called sample<br />

autocorrelation function (ACF):<br />

Definition 5.15 Sample Autocorrelation Function<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T }.<br />

The time series r t is weakly stationary. The k-lag sample autocorrelation is defined<br />

<strong>as</strong> the correlation between r t <strong>an</strong>d its p<strong>as</strong>t value r t−k :<br />

ˆρ k =<br />

∑ T<br />

t=k+1 (r t − ¯r)(r t−k − ¯r)<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 (r t − ¯r) 2 (5.39)<br />

The autocorrelation function is therefore a function in k.<br />

The sample autocorrelation is a bi<strong>as</strong>ed estimator for Definition C.16 of order (1/T ),<br />

i.e. for our sample of order 10 −4 <strong>an</strong>d therewith relatively small. The autocorrelation<br />

function for the DJ-AIGCI total return <strong>an</strong>d its pure commodity return components<br />

are plotted in the left diagrams of Figure 5.15 <strong>an</strong>d reported until the sixth lag in<br />

Table 5.10. The horizontal lines in Figure 5.15 give the 5% alpha levels, indicating<br />

signific<strong>an</strong>t autocorrelation.<br />

136


5.2 Properties of the DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

Figure 5.15: Autocorrelation <strong>an</strong>d Partial Autocorrelation Function of DJ-AIGCI Return<br />

Components<br />

The plot proofs our first impression gotten by Figure 5.14 that total <strong>an</strong>d spot returns<br />

don’t show autocorrelation pattern. In contr<strong>as</strong>t, roll return exhibit strong positive<br />

autocorrelation until the fourth lag, decre<strong>as</strong>ing with incre<strong>as</strong>ing lag. It is interesting<br />

that the correlation decre<strong>as</strong>es with 0.2 steps. Recall, the DJ-AIGCI rolling procedure<br />

rolls forward 20% of the futures per day over a five day period. Because the<br />

r<strong>an</strong>domness of price ch<strong>an</strong>ges are captured in spot returns <strong>an</strong>d the slow ch<strong>an</strong>ging,<br />

generally long term l<strong>as</strong>ting term structure is reflected by roll returns, this pattern<br />

c<strong>an</strong> be explained.<br />

Moreover, we calculated the so-called partial autocorrelation function (PACF). It<br />

removes the effect of shorter lag autocorrelation from the correlation estimate at<br />

longer lags <strong>an</strong>d is defined <strong>as</strong> follows:<br />

137


5 Properties of Commodity Returns<br />

Definition 5.16 Partial Autocorrelation Function<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T }.<br />

The time series r t is weakly stationary. The k-lag sample autocorrelation is defined<br />

<strong>as</strong> in Definition 5.15. The partial autocorrelation function is then defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

pρ ˆ kk = r k − ∑ k−1<br />

i=1 pρ ˆ k−1,i ˆρ k−1<br />

1 − ∑ k−1<br />

i=1 pρ ˆ<br />

(5.40)<br />

k−1,i ˆρ i<br />

In the right diagrams of Figure 5.15 we plotted the adequate PACFs for the three<br />

DJ-AIGCI return components.<br />

returns exhibit signific<strong>an</strong>t autocorrelation.<br />

The 20% rolling effect is removed but still, roll<br />

To be precise, we need to test jointly for signific<strong>an</strong>t autocorrelation. Therefore, the<br />

Box <strong>an</strong>d Pierce Test is excepted. It test the null hypothesis that the autocorrelation<br />

function <strong>as</strong> of Definition 5.15 of a time series until the m-th lag for all i ∈ 1, . . . , m<br />

is zero against the alternative that there is at le<strong>as</strong>t one i ∈ 1, . . . , m for that the<br />

autocorrelation function is not zero. The test statistic is defined <strong>as</strong> follows:<br />

Definition 5.17 Box <strong>an</strong>d Pierce Test<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a discrete r<strong>an</strong>dom sample of returns at times t ∈ {1, . . . , T }.<br />

The time series r t is weakly stationary. The k-lag sample autocorrelation is defined<br />

<strong>as</strong> in Definition 5.15. The Box <strong>an</strong>d Pierce test statistic is then defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

Q(k) = T<br />

k∑<br />

ˆρ 2 i (5.41)<br />

i=1<br />

Under the <strong>as</strong>sumption that {r 1 , . . . , r T } is independently <strong>an</strong>d identical distributed<br />

Q(k) is chi-squared distribution with m degrees of freedom.<br />

We performed the test for the DJ-AIGCI total return <strong>an</strong>d its pure commodity return<br />

components. Our results are documented in Table 5.10.<br />

DJ-AIGCI (TR) DJ-AIGCI (SP) DJ-AIGCI (RR)<br />

Lag i ˆρ i Statistic p Value ˆρ i Statistic p Value ˆρ i Statistic p Value<br />

1 1.00 0.16 69.04% 1.00 0.00 97.71% 1.00 1949.48 0.00%<br />

2 -0.01 1.02 60.19% 0.00 0.57 75.22% 0.71 3011.15 0.00%<br />

3 -0.01 1.13 76.87% -0.01 0.78 85.48% 0.52 3448.09 0.00%<br />

4 0.01 1.64 80.19% 0.01 1.35 85.35% 0.33 3546.22 0.00%<br />

5 -0.01 1.91 86.15% -0.01 1.39 92.55% 0.16 3546.87 0.00%<br />

6 0.01 8.05 23.46% 0.00 8.30 21.66% -0.01 3547.52 0.00%<br />

Table 5.10: Signific<strong>an</strong>ce Tests for Autocorrelation<br />

138


5.2 Properties of the DJ-AIGCI Return Components<br />

Not surprisingly, the test c<strong>an</strong>not be rejected for the total <strong>an</strong>d the spot return but for<br />

the roll return the test of no autocorrelation h<strong>as</strong> to be rejected. The results are in<br />

line with former findings of [Kat Oomen 2006]. Additionally, they found signific<strong>an</strong>t<br />

autocorrelation on single commodity futures returns including among others corn,<br />

soybe<strong>an</strong>s, live cattle, oil <strong>an</strong>d gold. Implicating, the property of autocorrelation gets<br />

lost in commodity index returns.<br />

139


6 <strong>Asset</strong> Allocation with Commodity Derivatives<br />

One of the most import<strong>an</strong>t decisions m<strong>an</strong>y people face is the choice where to invest<br />

their earned money for saving purposes. Generally, their individual needs are quite<br />

different: some may have relative short-term objectives, others may be saving to<br />

make college tuition payments in the medium term, yet others may be saving for<br />

retirement or to ensure the well-being of their heirs. Nevertheless, they all have one<br />

common decision to make: which <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses shall be allocated in my portfolio <strong>an</strong>d<br />

how much weight shall they get? Depending on the individual preferences, the degree<br />

of allocation in the single <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses vary. The process is even more complex<br />

when institutional investors come into consideration. They have generally to take<br />

care about legal restrictions on the one h<strong>an</strong>d but the pressure to reach return targets<br />

on the other h<strong>an</strong>d. We will investigate these questions in the following sections.<br />

Starting with Section 6.1, we will <strong>an</strong>alyze the risk premium of commodities with the<br />

purpose to categorize commodities <strong>as</strong> a separate <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s. Only if there exists a<br />

part of the risk premium embodied in commodity returns that c<strong>an</strong>not be explained<br />

by <strong>an</strong> other <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s’ returns, commodities c<strong>an</strong> be seen <strong>as</strong> independent investment<br />

opportunity. Second, we will <strong>an</strong>alyze the behavior of commodity returns in comparison<br />

to stock <strong>an</strong>d bond returns. As we have seen in Section 5.1.3 the most attractive<br />

risk <strong>an</strong>d return profiles c<strong>an</strong> only be reached by combining portfolio particip<strong>an</strong>ts with<br />

different return characteristics. The preceding sections have already uncovered that<br />

commodity returns have different risk <strong>an</strong>d return sources th<strong>an</strong> stock <strong>an</strong>d bond returns<br />

have, suspecting different return facilities. This shall be addressed in Section<br />

6.2 compactly. Finally, we will view commodities in the portfolio allocation process<br />

with stocks <strong>an</strong>d bonds in Section 6.3. We will stretch <strong>an</strong> efficient frontier that allows<br />

investors to pick the optimal <strong>as</strong>set allocation depending on their individual risk <strong>an</strong>d<br />

return preferences. Generally, the <strong>an</strong>alysis will show that allocating commodities to<br />

a traditional stock <strong>an</strong>d bond portfolio improves the characteristics of the investment.<br />

This is not re<strong>as</strong>oned by the extraordinary commodity returns of the l<strong>as</strong>t years but in<br />

the attractive risk <strong>an</strong>d correlation characteristics commodity returns have to stock<br />

<strong>an</strong>d bond returns.<br />

6.1 Me<strong>an</strong> Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Sp<strong>an</strong>ning<br />

The first question to <strong>an</strong>swer in investment practice is whether the investment medium<br />

c<strong>an</strong> be seen <strong>as</strong> a separate investment cl<strong>as</strong>s or not. If it c<strong>an</strong> be seen <strong>as</strong> a separate<br />

<strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s the second step is to categorize it <strong>as</strong> traditional or alternative <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s.<br />

140


6.1 Me<strong>an</strong> Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Sp<strong>an</strong>ning<br />

Following [Greer 1997] commodities account into the group of alternative <strong>as</strong>sets.<br />

Furthermore, he distinguishes between three super <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses, including ”capital<br />

<strong>as</strong>sets”, ”<strong>as</strong>set that c<strong>an</strong> be used <strong>as</strong> economic inputs” <strong>an</strong>d ”<strong>as</strong>sets that are a store of<br />

value”. The first group consists of all fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>sets whose value is determined by<br />

their future c<strong>as</strong>h flows. They provide a source of ongoing value. As a result, this<br />

<strong>as</strong>sets are valued b<strong>as</strong>ed on the net present value of their expected returns. Equities<br />

<strong>an</strong>d bonds are the main representatives of this group. But also hedge funds, private<br />

equity funds <strong>an</strong>d credit derivatives are included because their value is determined by<br />

the present value of the expected future c<strong>as</strong>h flows from the securities in which they<br />

invest. The second group called ”<strong>as</strong>sets that c<strong>an</strong> be used <strong>as</strong> economic inputs” c<strong>an</strong> be<br />

consumed <strong>as</strong> part of the production cycle. Deducting form Section 2, commodities<br />

count into this group. Additionally, we have already seen in Section 3 that these<br />

<strong>as</strong>sets c<strong>an</strong>not be valued using a simple net present value approach. Finally, commodities<br />

like gold <strong>an</strong>d silver count, amongst others e.g. art, into the third group.<br />

Owning jewelery or gold bars don’t produce future c<strong>as</strong>h flows. But especially in<br />

the emerging parts of the world these <strong>as</strong>sets are a medium of maintaining wealth.<br />

In these countries, residents don’t have access to the same r<strong>an</strong>ge of fin<strong>an</strong>cial products<br />

that are available to residents of more developed nations. Consequently, they<br />

accumulate their wealth through a t<strong>an</strong>gible <strong>as</strong>set <strong>as</strong> opposed to a capital <strong>as</strong>set.<br />

The example of gold shows that the lines between the three super <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses c<strong>an</strong><br />

become blurred. However, what is <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s <strong>an</strong>yway in the correct statistical<br />

interpretation? Following [DeRoon Nijm<strong>an</strong> 2001] <strong>an</strong>y suspected <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s r i that<br />

actually earns a risk premium above c<strong>as</strong>h c that c<strong>an</strong>not be explained by other<br />

already existing <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses r j is actually <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s in its own right. The<br />

following definition shall give the correct mathematical expl<strong>an</strong>ation: 138<br />

Definition 6.1 Me<strong>an</strong> Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Sp<strong>an</strong>ning<br />

Let r i denote the return of a representative of the suspected <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s, let c denote<br />

the return of c<strong>as</strong>h, e.g. Tre<strong>as</strong>ury Bills, <strong>an</strong>d let r j denote the return of other <strong>as</strong>set<br />

cl<strong>as</strong>ses. The suspected <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s c<strong>an</strong> be seen <strong>as</strong> a separate <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s if the α<br />

coefficient of the following regression is statistically signific<strong>an</strong>t:<br />

n∑<br />

r i − c = α + β j (r j − c) + ε (6.1)<br />

j=1<br />

Definition 6.1 shows that <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s c<strong>an</strong> be seen <strong>as</strong> separate if there is a part<br />

of the risk premium that c<strong>an</strong>not be explained by other <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses. Following<br />

138 For details about solving such regression models see Definition 5.3 <strong>an</strong>d Theorem 5.1.<br />

141


6 <strong>Asset</strong> Allocation with Commodity Derivatives<br />

Equation (5.14) the higher the correlation between two <strong>as</strong>sets, the more systematic<br />

common risk exposure <strong>an</strong>d hence common risk premium exists.<br />

For our <strong>an</strong>alysis we used the DJ-AIGCI total return index, the S&P 500 total return<br />

index <strong>an</strong>d the J.P. Morg<strong>an</strong> USA Government Bond Index. As shown in Section 4.4<br />

the total return of a commodity index is summed up by the excess return <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

interest rate return earned on collateral. Following [DJAIGCI 2006] Dow Jones uses<br />

US Tre<strong>as</strong>ury Bill’s returns to calculate the total return index. To be consistent we<br />

used this return <strong>as</strong> c<strong>as</strong>h in the regression. Table 6.1 summarizes our results for the<br />

period (1991-2006). A statistically signific<strong>an</strong>t regression coefficient is marked with<br />

a ”∗”.<br />

Value t-value p-value<br />

α 0.000166 1.298 0.19453<br />

β Stocks -0.00865 -0.68 0.49585<br />

β Bonds -0.15454* -3.47 0.0005<br />

Table 6.1: Me<strong>an</strong> Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Sp<strong>an</strong>ning Coefficients (1991-2006)<br />

Unfortunately, we c<strong>an</strong>not identify a statistically signific<strong>an</strong>t risk premium. Similar<br />

research done by Deutsche B<strong>an</strong>k using the same traditional reference indices <strong>as</strong> we<br />

did, identified over the period from J<strong>an</strong>uary 1989 to J<strong>an</strong>uary 2005 no statistically<br />

signific<strong>an</strong>t risk premium for the GSCI but for the DBLCI <strong>an</strong>d the DBLCI-MR. As<br />

already known, commodities went through a regression through the 1990th <strong>an</strong>d first<br />

became attractive for investing at the beginning of the 21rst century. Therefore, we<br />

performed the same <strong>an</strong>alysis for the period (2002-2006). The results are documented<br />

in Table 6.2.<br />

Value t-value p-value<br />

α 0.000592* 2.022 0.044<br />

β Stocks 0.049133 1.674 0.0944<br />

β Bonds 0.040089 0.410 0.6819<br />

Table 6.2: Me<strong>an</strong> Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Sp<strong>an</strong>ning Coefficients (2002-2006)<br />

Over the smaller period we identified a small 139<br />

premium.<br />

but statistically signific<strong>an</strong>t risk<br />

139 But recall, the <strong>an</strong>alysis is in daily scale.<br />

142


6.1 Me<strong>an</strong> Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Sp<strong>an</strong>ning<br />

Furthermore, this <strong>an</strong>alysis show the time dependent character of commodity investment.<br />

Because commodities don’t provide future c<strong>as</strong>h flows <strong>an</strong>d are not valued by<br />

discounted c<strong>as</strong>h flow methods their perform<strong>an</strong>ce is highly dependent to scarcity embodied<br />

in the convenience yield or risk premium on inventories. Moreover, we have<br />

seen that commodity markets have been in cont<strong>an</strong>go more often th<strong>an</strong> in backwardation<br />

producing negative roll returns with a major impact on the total excess return<br />

perform<strong>an</strong>ce.<br />

Finally, we performed again a factor <strong>an</strong>alysis following Definition 5.3 with different<br />

representatives of the three <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses under consideration. We used respectively<br />

three indices of the traditional <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses including a USA only, a Europe only <strong>an</strong>d<br />

a global index. As representatives for the bond market we took the J. P. Morg<strong>an</strong><br />

US Government Bond Index, the J. P. Morg<strong>an</strong> Europe Government Bond Index <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the the J. P. Morg<strong>an</strong> Global Government Bond Index. The S&P 500 Total Return,<br />

the MSCI World <strong>an</strong>d the MSCI Europe serve <strong>as</strong> examples for the stock market.<br />

Again, the DJ-AIGCI total return represents the commodity exposure. Figure 6.1<br />

summarizes our findings:<br />

Figure 6.1: Factor Analysis with other <strong>Asset</strong> Cl<strong>as</strong>ses (1991-2006)<br />

We identified three common risk factors. The bond indices stick out in one direction<br />

what we therefore identify <strong>as</strong> the risk factor mainly influencing a bond investment.<br />

The second dimension is uniquely stretched by the stock indices resulting to our conclusion<br />

that this is the risk factor driving the stock returns. Finally, the DJ-AIGCI<br />

protrudes in his own direction. We deduce that this might symbolize a separate<br />

143


6 <strong>Asset</strong> Allocation with Commodity Derivatives<br />

commodity risk factor, although the DJ-AIGCI additionally sticks out in the bond<br />

direction. This finding is in line with the me<strong>an</strong> vari<strong>an</strong>ce sp<strong>an</strong>ning result <strong>as</strong> reported<br />

in Table 6.1.<br />

Summing up, the section showed that commodities tend to be a separate <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s<br />

that produced a statistically signific<strong>an</strong>t risk premium over selected periods <strong>an</strong>d is<br />

driven by its own risk factors. This promises diversification effects in the portfolio<br />

context with the traditional <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses stocks <strong>an</strong>d bonds.<br />

6.2 Dependence to Stocks, Bonds <strong>an</strong>d Inflation<br />

After we identified commodities <strong>as</strong> a separate <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s we need to take a deeper<br />

look into their perform<strong>an</strong>ce over the period under consideration. In Figure 6.2 we<br />

plotted the development of <strong>an</strong> 100 US dollar investment into the three <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses<br />

stocks, bonds <strong>an</strong>d commodities at the 01.01.1991. 140 Additionally, inflation is drawn<br />

in to show that all <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses have outperformed the natural value loss of money<br />

over time.<br />

Figure 6.2: Perform<strong>an</strong>ce of different <strong>Asset</strong> Cl<strong>as</strong>ses<br />

On the first view we realize that all three <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses have outperformed inflation,<br />

implicating that investment in general payed off over the l<strong>as</strong>t years. Stocks produced<br />

the highest return with a total value gain of around 433% followed by a fully collateralized<br />

commodity investment with a total value gain of around 228% <strong>an</strong>d latest<br />

bonds with a total value gain of around 176%. Moreover, Table 6.3 summarized the<br />

140 The calculation followed Definition C.3.<br />

144


6.2 Dependence to Stocks, Bonds <strong>an</strong>d Inflation<br />

key statistics of the investment opportunities.<br />

DJ-AIGCI S&P 500 JPM Bond USA<br />

Annualized arithmetic me<strong>an</strong> 7.63% 10.73% 6.50%<br />

Total value gain 228.18% 433.09% 175.57%<br />

Annualized st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation 12.64% 15.91% 4.54%<br />

Minimum (daily) -9.15% -7.11% -1.61%<br />

Maximum (daily) 4.85 % 5.58% 1.59%<br />

Me<strong>an</strong> (daily) 0.03 % 0.04% 0.03%<br />

Medi<strong>an</strong> (daily) 0.04 % 0.04% 0.03%<br />

99% VaR -2.03 % -2.62% -0.78%<br />

95% VaR -1.24 % -1.58% -0.45%<br />

Table 6.3: Key Statistics of different <strong>Asset</strong> Cl<strong>as</strong>ses’ Returns (1991-2006)<br />

Recall from Table 5.5, the average excess return of commodities w<strong>as</strong> on average<br />

3.70% per <strong>an</strong>num, i.e. the 7.63% average commodity total return per <strong>an</strong>num consists<br />

of 48.5% commodity excess return <strong>an</strong>d 51.5% interest rate return earned on<br />

collateral. Therewith, only a fully collateralized commodity investment produced a<br />

return situated in the middle of stock <strong>an</strong>d bond returns. There are different research<br />

papers, including [Gorton Rouwenhorst 2004] <strong>an</strong>d [PIMCO 2006], identifying commodities<br />

<strong>as</strong> the best performing <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s over the long run. Both studies start<br />

at the beginning of the 1970th <strong>as</strong> commodities run into their first huge price surge<br />

<strong>an</strong>d end 2004 in the middle of the second huge commodity price surge. During the<br />

whole period stock perform<strong>an</strong>ce is characterized by a steady growth interrupted by<br />

the regression period at the end of the 1990th <strong>an</strong>d the bull period at the beginning<br />

of the 21st century. For inst<strong>an</strong>ce, [PIMCO 2006] reported <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>nualized arithmetic<br />

return of 14.06% for commodities <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>nualized arithmetic return of 12.60% for<br />

stocks. Additionally, literature <strong>an</strong>d our <strong>an</strong>alysis shows that commodity investment<br />

shall be long term orientated conforming findings of [Till 2000] <strong>as</strong> reported in Section<br />

5.1.1.<br />

In Section 5.1.3 we introduced the free lunch in fin<strong>an</strong>ce: diversification. The main<br />

purpose of <strong>as</strong>set allocation is to improve the risk return profile of <strong>an</strong> investors portfolio.<br />

Theorem 5.2 uncovered the main driver of diversification: the average covari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

or respective its normalized brother the average correlation of the portfolio<br />

constituencies. Following Definition 5.1 <strong>an</strong>d Definition 5.2 we calculated Pearson’s<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Kendall’s correlation coefficient between the three <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses <strong>an</strong>d reported<br />

145


6 <strong>Asset</strong> Allocation with Commodity Derivatives<br />

the results in Table 6.4. Additionally, the correlations to inflation are reported. 141<br />

DJ-AIGCI S&P 500 JPM Bond USA Inflation<br />

DJ-AIGCI 1.00 -0.01 -0.06* 0.13<br />

S&P 500 -0.00 1.00 -0.03* -0.09<br />

JPM Bond USA -0.04* 0.04* 1.00 -0.07<br />

Inflation 0.09 -0.08 -0.04 1.00<br />

Table 6.4: Kendall/Pearson Correlation between Different <strong>Asset</strong> Cl<strong>as</strong>ses <strong>an</strong>d Inflation<br />

In the left lower rect<strong>an</strong>gle of Table 6.4 the Kendall correlation coefficient is reported<br />

<strong>an</strong>d in the right upper rect<strong>an</strong>gle the Pearson correlation coefficient is entered. We<br />

highlighted statistically signific<strong>an</strong>t values with a ”∗”.<br />

Commodity returns don’t show correlation pattern to the traditional <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses,<br />

i.e. the correlation coefficients are nearby zero. On the contrary, to bond returns<br />

they exhibit a negative dependence structure. In the portfolio context, this adverse<br />

pattern promises diversification effects <strong>an</strong>d we will address ourselves to this problem<br />

in Section 6.3.<br />

Our findings are in line with p<strong>as</strong>t research. [Gorton Rouwenhorst 2004] extended the<br />

<strong>an</strong>alysis <strong>an</strong>d showed the Pearson correlation coefficient for average returns taken over<br />

different time frames, including monthly, quarterly, one year <strong>an</strong>d five years. They<br />

showed that the <strong>an</strong>ti correlation rises with incre<strong>as</strong>ing time period. This suggests that<br />

the diversification benefits of commodities tend to be larger for longer horizons.<br />

Investors ultimately care about the real purch<strong>as</strong>ing power of their returns, which<br />

me<strong>an</strong>s that the threat of inflation is a concern for investors. Table 6.4 shows that<br />

traditional <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses are a poor hedge against inflation. Only commodities have<br />

a positive correlation to inflation indicating positive price movements coming in line<br />

with incre<strong>as</strong>ing inflation. This is not <strong>as</strong>tonishing because commodities are real <strong>as</strong>sets.<br />

Inflation is me<strong>as</strong>ured <strong>as</strong> the ch<strong>an</strong>ge of a product b<strong>as</strong>ket’s value. But products<br />

are made of commodities explaining the co-movement of inflation <strong>an</strong>d commodity<br />

prices. [Gorton Rouwenhorst 2004] extended the <strong>an</strong>alysis <strong>an</strong>d calculated the Pearson<br />

correlation coefficient to the above described average returns for different time<br />

periods. Again, they could show that the correlation incre<strong>as</strong>es over time. Moreover,<br />

they divided inflation in its expected <strong>an</strong>d unexpected part. For it, they used a<br />

141 Inflation is me<strong>as</strong>ured in monthly scale. Linear interpolating to daily values would destroy the<br />

actual dependence structure. Therefore, the correlation coefficients of the three <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses to<br />

inflation are calculated with monthly data.<br />

146


6.2 Dependence to Stocks, Bonds <strong>an</strong>d Inflation<br />

model suggested by [Fama Schwert 1977] <strong>an</strong>d [Schwert 1981]. The short term Tre<strong>as</strong>ury<br />

Bill’s rate is a proxy for the market’s expectation of inflation, if the expected<br />

real rate of interest is const<strong>an</strong>t over time. Consequently, unexpected inflation c<strong>an</strong><br />

be me<strong>as</strong>ured <strong>as</strong> the actual inflation rate minus the nominal interest rate which is<br />

known ex <strong>an</strong>te. They showed that the negative sensitivities of stocks <strong>an</strong>d bonds <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the positive sensitivities of commodities are higher to unexpected inflation th<strong>an</strong> to<br />

inflation itself.<br />

To close the section, the following <strong>an</strong>alysis shall give <strong>an</strong>other interesting inside into<br />

the behavior of commodity returns. Stock returns are getting more volatile in falling<br />

markets, i.e. stock returns <strong>an</strong>d their volatility are negatively correlated. This pattern<br />

c<strong>an</strong> be seen in Table 6.5 <strong>an</strong>d is known <strong>as</strong> ”leverage effect”. Following Definition 5.1<br />

we calculated the Pearson correlation coefficient between the average return <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the average volatility over a time lag of five, 20 <strong>an</strong>d 60 days. Again statistically<br />

signific<strong>an</strong>t values are marked with a ”∗”.<br />

DJ-AIGCI (ER) DJ-AIGCI (TR) S&P 500 JPM Bond USA<br />

5 days 0.00 0.00 -0.10* -0.17*<br />

20 days 0.04* 0.03* -0.21* -0.26*<br />

60 days 0.15* 0.14* -0.33* -0.27*<br />

Table 6.5: Pearson Correlation between average Return <strong>an</strong>d Volatility<br />

While stock <strong>an</strong>d bond returns are getting more nervous in falling markets, commodity<br />

returns exhibit the adverse pattern: they are getting more nervous in rising<br />

markets. This phenomena w<strong>as</strong> already discussed in Section 5.1 <strong>an</strong>d named by<br />

[Germ<strong>an</strong> 2005] <strong>as</strong> the ”negative leverage effect”. Recall, price surges in commodity<br />

markets come in line with falling inventories <strong>an</strong>d the fear of possible supply interruptions.<br />

This makes the market nervous <strong>an</strong>d volatility rising. In contr<strong>as</strong>t, stocks<br />

<strong>an</strong>d bonds are valued by future c<strong>as</strong>h flows. Falling prices indicate comp<strong>an</strong>y <strong>an</strong>d<br />

issuer problems exciting sells that incre<strong>as</strong>es the volatility.<br />

This <strong>an</strong>ti-cyclical pattern gives again evidence to suggest that the combination of<br />

stocks, bonds <strong>an</strong>d commodities yield to attractive risk <strong>an</strong>d return profiles of a portfolio.<br />

147


6 <strong>Asset</strong> Allocation with Commodity Derivatives<br />

6.3 Portfolio Optimization<br />

The l<strong>as</strong>t two sections introduced the historical perform<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d return characteristics<br />

of commodities <strong>an</strong>d their dependence structure to traditional <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s’ returns,<br />

i.e. stock <strong>an</strong>d bond returns. We will close this section with a brief <strong>an</strong>alysis of<br />

the interaction of all three <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses in the portfolio context. Our findings from<br />

Section 6.2 already suspected positive diversification effects, commodities could generate<br />

in a traditional stock <strong>an</strong>d bond portfolio. The b<strong>as</strong>ic tool for calculating <strong>as</strong>set<br />

allocation is Harry Markowitz’s me<strong>an</strong> vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimization first published in<br />

[Markowitz 1952]. The idea is to construct a portfolio that h<strong>as</strong> maximum return<br />

b<strong>as</strong>ed on the constrain of a predefined risk boundary depending on the risk aversion<br />

of the investor. Imagine n <strong>as</strong>sets under consideration. Denote <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set’s weight in the<br />

portfolio with x i , i = 1, . . . , n, its average return with µ <strong>as</strong> defined in Definition C.10.<br />

The covari<strong>an</strong>ce matrix including the <strong>as</strong>set’s vari<strong>an</strong>ces <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.11 at the<br />

main diagonal <strong>an</strong>d the covari<strong>an</strong>ces among the <strong>as</strong>sets <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.14 on the<br />

non diagonal entries be denoted by (C) i,j=1,...,n . The mathematical formulation of<br />

the Markowitz’s me<strong>an</strong> vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimization is given <strong>as</strong>:<br />

⎧<br />

⎪⎨ µ T x −→ max<br />

P µ = x<br />

⎪⎩<br />

T Cx = ¯σ 2<br />

(6.2)<br />

1 T x = 1 with 1 = (1, . . . , 1) T<br />

Alternatively, the problem c<strong>an</strong> be re-written to construct a portfolio that h<strong>as</strong> minimum<br />

risk, i.e. vari<strong>an</strong>ce, under the constrain that a predefined return is still generated:<br />

⎧<br />

⎪⎨ x T Cx −→ min<br />

P σ 2 = µ<br />

⎪⎩<br />

T x = ¯µ<br />

(6.3)<br />

1 T x = 1 with 1 = (1, . . . , 1) T<br />

The problem’s solution requires three input factor: me<strong>an</strong>s, st<strong>an</strong>dard deviations respectively<br />

volatilities <strong>an</strong>d correlations respectively covari<strong>an</strong>ces. B<strong>as</strong>ed on these three<br />

inputs, en efficient frontier is constructed in which each point maximizes the return<br />

per unit risk. This provides investors with individual risk <strong>an</strong>d return guidelines with<br />

the adequate portfolio composition ˜x. The mathematical solution of P σ 2 <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

representation of the efficient frontier is given in Theorem 6.1.<br />

Theorem 6.1 Me<strong>an</strong> Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Optimization<br />

Denote with C the covari<strong>an</strong>ce matrix which is <strong>as</strong>sumed to be positive definite. Moreover,<br />

define µ <strong>as</strong> is Definition C.10 <strong>an</strong>d denote:<br />

148


6.3 Portfolio Optimization<br />

a = 1 T C −1 µ, b = µ T C −1 µ, c = 1 T C −1 1, d = bc − a 2<br />

The optimal solution of P σ 2<br />

is given <strong>as</strong>:<br />

˜x = 1 d<br />

(<br />

(c¯µ − a)C −1 µ + (b − a¯µ)C −1 1 ) (6.4)<br />

with<br />

σ 2 (¯µ) = ˜x T C ˜x = c¯µ2 − 2a¯µ + b<br />

d<br />

The Minimum Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Portfolio denoted with x MV P is given <strong>as</strong>:<br />

(6.5)<br />

x MV P = 1 c C−1 1 (6.6)<br />

It is located in the risk return space at:<br />

(µ MV P , σ MV P ) = ( a c , √<br />

1<br />

c ) (6.7)<br />

The efficient frontier is given <strong>as</strong>:<br />

¯µ = µ MV P ±<br />

√<br />

d<br />

c (σ2 − σ 2 MV P ) (6.8)<br />

Note, the negative c<strong>as</strong>e of the efficient frontier of Equation (6.8) is dominated by<br />

the positive c<strong>as</strong>e <strong>an</strong>d therefore, c<strong>an</strong> be categorized <strong>as</strong> not efficient. Anticipating<br />

Figure 6.3, compare the two portfolios with risk equal to 4.9% <strong>an</strong>nualized st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

deviations. In the negative c<strong>as</strong>e it produces <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>nualized return of around 6.6%,<br />

but in the positive c<strong>as</strong>e it produces <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>nualized return of around 7.5%. Following,<br />

the positive c<strong>as</strong>e portfolio will be chosen because although taking the same risk <strong>as</strong><br />

in the negative c<strong>as</strong>e, more return is generated.<br />

Proof:<br />

Because C −1 is positive definite, it follows:<br />

b = µ T C −1 µ > 0 (6.9)<br />

<strong>an</strong>d furthermore:<br />

c = 1 T C −1 1 > 0 (6.10)<br />

With the scalar product < x, y >≡ x T C −1 y, the Chauchy-Schwarz inequation <strong>an</strong>d<br />

149


6 <strong>Asset</strong> Allocation with Commodity Derivatives<br />

x ≡ 1, y ≡ µ follows:<br />

< x, y > 2 = (1 T C −1 µ) 2 = a 2<br />

< < x, x >< y, y >= (1 T C −1 1)(µ T C −1 µ) = bc<br />

⇔<br />

d = bc − a 2 > 0 (6.11)<br />

Furthermore, the Lagr<strong>an</strong>ge function is given <strong>as</strong>:<br />

L(x, u) = 1 2 xT Cx + u 1 (¯µ − µ T x) + u 2 (1 − 1 T x) (6.12)<br />

˜x is optimal for P if there exists <strong>an</strong> u = (u 1 , u 2 ) T<br />

Kuhn-Tucker conditions:<br />

∈ R that satisfies the so-called<br />

∂L<br />

∂x i<br />

(˜x, u) =<br />

n∑<br />

c i,j ˜x j − u 1 µ i − u 2 = 0 (6.13)<br />

j=1<br />

∂L<br />

(˜x, u)<br />

∂u 1<br />

= ¯µ − µ T ˜x = 0 (6.14)<br />

∂L<br />

(˜x, u)<br />

∂u 2<br />

= 1 − 1 T x = 0 (6.15)<br />

(6.13) ⇔ C ˜x = u 1 µ + u 2 1<br />

⇔ ˜x = u 1 C −1 µ + u 2 C −1 1<br />

(6.16)<br />

(6.15)&(6.16)<br />

{}}{<br />

⇒ 1 T ˜x = u 1 1 T C −1 µ<br />

} {{ }<br />

≡a<br />

+ u 2 1 T C −1 1 } {{ }<br />

≡c<br />

= au 1 + cu 2<br />

(6.15)<br />

{}}{<br />

= 1<br />

(6.17)<br />

(6.14)&(6.16)<br />

{}}{<br />

⇒ µ T ˜x = u 1 µ T C −1 µ<br />

} {{ }<br />

≡b<br />

+ u 2 µ T C −1 1<br />

} {{ }<br />

≡a<br />

= bu 1 + au 2<br />

(6.14)<br />

{}}{<br />

= ¯µ<br />

(6.18)<br />

(6.17)&(6.18)<br />

{}}{<br />

⇔<br />

(<br />

a<br />

c<br />

) (<br />

}<br />

b a<br />

{{ }<br />

≡A<br />

)<br />

u 1<br />

u 2<br />

} {{ }<br />

≡u<br />

=<br />

(<br />

1<br />

¯µ<br />

)<br />

(6.19)<br />

150


6.3 Portfolio Optimization<br />

Calculate the inverse of A <strong>as</strong>:<br />

A −1 =<br />

1<br />

det(A)<br />

=<br />

1<br />

bc − a 2<br />

} {{ }<br />

≡−d<br />

=<br />

1<br />

d<br />

(<br />

(<br />

(<br />

a<br />

−b<br />

a<br />

−b<br />

−a<br />

b<br />

)<br />

−c<br />

a<br />

)<br />

−c<br />

a<br />

)<br />

c<br />

−a<br />

(6.20)<br />

With (6.19) <strong>an</strong>d (6.20) follows:<br />

( )<br />

u = A −1 1<br />

¯µ<br />

(<br />

= 1 c¯µ − a<br />

d b − a¯µ<br />

)<br />

(6.21)<br />

Putting (6.21) into (6.16) yields to Equation (6.4), the optimal solution ˜x of P σ 2:<br />

˜x<br />

(6.16)<br />

{}}{<br />

= u 1 C −1 µ + u 2 C −1 1<br />

(6.21)<br />

{}}{<br />

= 1 d ((c¯µ − a)C−1 µ + (b − a¯µ)C −1 1)<br />

With it, Equation (6.5) follows with:<br />

σ 2 (¯µ) = ˜x T C ˜x<br />

(6.13)<br />

{}}{<br />

= u 1 µ T ˜x + u 2 1 T ˜x<br />

(6.17)&(6.18)<br />

{}}{<br />

= u 1¯µ + u 2<br />

(6.21)<br />

{}}{<br />

=<br />

=<br />

1<br />

((c¯µ − a)¯µ + (b − a¯µ))<br />

d<br />

c¯µ 2 − 2a¯µ + b<br />

d<br />

Furthermore, the minimum of Equation (6.5) yields to the Minimum Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Portfolio<br />

denoted with x MV P , i.e. Equation (6.6), <strong>an</strong>d its points in the risk return space,<br />

151


6 <strong>Asset</strong> Allocation with Commodity Derivatives<br />

i.e. Equation (6.7):<br />

∂σ 2 (¯µ)<br />

∂ ¯µ<br />

= 1 (2c¯µ − 2a) ≡ 0<br />

d<br />

⇒ µ MV P = a c<br />

(6.22)<br />

To check for a minimum, the second partial derivative is positive:<br />

∂ 2 σ 2 (¯µ)<br />

∂ 2¯µ<br />

=<br />

2c<br />

d<br />

(6.10)&(6.11)<br />

{}}{<br />

> 0<br />

Putting this into Equation (6.5) yields to:<br />

σ MV P = √ σ 2 (µ MV P )<br />

√<br />

(6.5)<br />

{}}{ cµ<br />

2<br />

=<br />

MV P<br />

− 2aµ MV P + b<br />

(6.22)<br />

{}}{<br />

=<br />

√<br />

d<br />

c ( )<br />

a 2 (<br />

c − 2a a<br />

)<br />

c + b<br />

d<br />

=<br />

√<br />

1<br />

c<br />

Together we have shown Equation (6.7), the location of the Minimum Vari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

Portfolio in the risk return space:<br />

(µ MV P , σ MV P ) = ( a c , √<br />

1<br />

c )<br />

To find the Minimum Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Portfolio x MV P respectively the weights of the Minimum<br />

Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Portfolio coded in x MV P , we put Equation (6.7) into Equation (6.4):<br />

(6.4)<br />

{}}{<br />

x MV P = 1 (<br />

(cµMV P − a)C −1 µ + (b − aµ MV P )C −1 1 )<br />

d<br />

(6.22)<br />

{}}{<br />

= 1 ( ( a<br />

)<br />

( a<br />

) )<br />

(c − a)C −1 µ + (b − a )C −1 1<br />

d c c<br />

= 1 c C−1 1<br />

152


6.3 Portfolio Optimization<br />

Finally, the efficient frontier is calculated from Equation (6.5), whereby we have to<br />

define σ ≡ σ(¯µ):<br />

(6.5)<br />

σ 2 {}}{<br />

=<br />

c¯µ 2 − 2a¯µ + b<br />

d<br />

⇔<br />

d<br />

c σ2 = ¯µ 2 − 2 a c ¯µ + b c<br />

(<br />

= ¯µ − a ) 2 a 2<br />

−<br />

c<br />

c 2 + b c } {{ }<br />

bc−a 2<br />

c 2<br />

(6.22)&(6.11)<br />

{}}{<br />

= (¯µ − µ MV P ) 2 + d 1<br />

c c<br />

= (¯µ − µ MV P ) 2 + d c σ2 MV P<br />

⇔<br />

(¯µ − µ MV P ) 2 =<br />

⇔<br />

d<br />

c (σ2 − σ 2 MV P )<br />

¯µ = µ MV P ±<br />

√<br />

d<br />

c (σ2 − σ 2 MV P )<br />

Following Theorem 6.1 we calculated the efficient frontier with <strong>an</strong>d without commodities.<br />

For it, we took the <strong>an</strong>nualized me<strong>an</strong>s over the period 1991 until 2006, i.e.<br />

caused by the time additivity of log returns this is equal to taking rolling averages<br />

over one year periods, <strong>an</strong>d linear correlations of stock, bond <strong>an</strong>d commodity returns<br />

<strong>as</strong> reported in Table 6.4. Our results are shown in Figure 6.3. The red line represents<br />

the efficient frontier with commodities <strong>an</strong>d the brown line draws the efficient<br />

frontier without commodities.<br />

✷<br />

The efficient frontier with commodities is superior to the efficient frontier without<br />

commodities, i.e. including commodities in the opportunity set improved the risk<br />

<strong>an</strong>d return tradeoff over the entire risk levels under consideration. If <strong>an</strong> investor had<br />

invested into a portfolio including commodities, he would have realized the different<br />

return expectations with lower risk amounting on average to 0.77% <strong>an</strong>nualized st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

deviation. The Minimum Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Portfolio decre<strong>as</strong>ed in risk around 0.8%<br />

<strong>an</strong>nualized st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation. This is shown in Figure 6.3: the Minimum Vari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

Portfolio (MV P ) without commodities h<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>nualized st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation<br />

of around 4.5% whereby the Minimum Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Portfolio (MV P c ) with commodities<br />

h<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>nualized st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation of around 3.8%. Implicating, including<br />

153


6 <strong>Asset</strong> Allocation with Commodity Derivatives<br />

Figure 6.3: Efficient Frontiers with <strong>an</strong>d without <strong>Commodities</strong> (1991-2006)<br />

commodities into the <strong>as</strong>set allocation improves the risk structure in comparison to<br />

a portfolio only including traditional <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses.<br />

An other interesting inside into the team play of the three <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses in a portfolio<br />

gives <strong>an</strong> efficient frontier area graph <strong>as</strong> in Figure 6.4. It display the ch<strong>an</strong>ge<br />

of the <strong>as</strong>set weights ˜x of the efficient frontier across the entire risk spectrum. Consequently,<br />

the efficient frontier area graph is similar to a st<strong>an</strong>dard <strong>as</strong>set allocation<br />

pie chart that shows the <strong>as</strong>set allocation that corresponds to a particular spot on<br />

the efficient frontier, except the efficient frontier area graph displays all of the <strong>as</strong>set<br />

allocations on the efficient frontier. It is helpful to identify the substitution of the<br />

different <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses over the different risk levels. The black bar in the respective<br />

diagram of Figure 6.4 represents the Minimum Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Portfolio’s <strong>as</strong>set allocation.<br />

All weighting combinations on its right side yield to efficient risk <strong>an</strong>d return profiles<br />

of the resulting portfolio, i.e. the respective <strong>as</strong>set allocation yield to risk <strong>an</strong>d return<br />

profiles of the positive c<strong>as</strong>e in Equation 6.8.<br />

The left diagram in Figure 6.4 shows the <strong>as</strong>set allocation of traditional portfolios<br />

only including stocks <strong>an</strong>d bonds. It is not <strong>as</strong>tonishing that with incre<strong>as</strong>ing stock<br />

allocation the portfolios’ risk rises. The Minimum Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Portfolio consists of<br />

11.8% stocks <strong>an</strong>d 88.4% bonds. The right diagram in Figure 6.4 shows the allocation<br />

of a portfolio including stocks, bonds <strong>an</strong>d commodities. Over the entire risk<br />

r<strong>an</strong>ge commodities are allocated positively r<strong>an</strong>ging from 14.9% in the Minimum<br />

Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Portfolio until 27.7% in a high risk portfolio. Not until a st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation<br />

of around 12% per <strong>an</strong>num, commodities are substituted by stocks <strong>as</strong> well.<br />

This is not <strong>as</strong>tonishing when comparing the input parameters of Table 6.3. At the<br />

154


6.3 Portfolio Optimization<br />

Figure 6.4: Comparison of Portfolio Allocation<br />

right end of the efficient frontier a complete stock portfolio <strong>as</strong> riskiest opportunity<br />

is located.<br />

The historical me<strong>an</strong> vari<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>alysis h<strong>as</strong> shown that commodities are <strong>an</strong> essential<br />

part of the <strong>as</strong>set allocation if portfolios shall be generated that have superior risk<br />

<strong>an</strong>d return profiles in comparison to stock <strong>an</strong>d bond only portfolios. But we have<br />

to take the ever-present disclaimer into consideration that ”p<strong>as</strong>t perform<strong>an</strong>ce is no<br />

guar<strong>an</strong>tee of future perform<strong>an</strong>ce”. Moreover, me<strong>an</strong> vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimization is very<br />

sensitive to the estimates of returns, st<strong>an</strong>dard deviations <strong>an</strong>d correlations. 142 But<br />

of the three inputs required to create <strong>an</strong> efficient frontier, returns are by far the<br />

most import<strong>an</strong>t, <strong>an</strong>d unfortunately, the le<strong>as</strong>t stable. [Chopra Ziemba 1993] estimated<br />

that at a moderate risk level, me<strong>an</strong> vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimization is 11 times more<br />

sensitive to small ch<strong>an</strong>ges in returns relative to small ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the risk me<strong>as</strong>ure<br />

st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation. Furthermore, me<strong>an</strong> vari<strong>an</strong>ce optimization is two times more<br />

sensitive to small ch<strong>an</strong>ges in risk relative to small ch<strong>an</strong>ges in correlations. We c<strong>an</strong><br />

<strong>as</strong>sume that the underlying historical correlation structure between the traditional<br />

<strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses <strong>an</strong>d commodities will not fundamentally ch<strong>an</strong>ge because it is not expected<br />

that the underlying economic dependence structure between the traditional<br />

<strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses <strong>an</strong>d commodities will ch<strong>an</strong>ge. Expected returns are not that stable.<br />

Therefore, we calculated the minimum <strong>an</strong>nual return, commodities should produce<br />

to be allocated with stocks <strong>an</strong>d bonds in a portfolio, the so-called Hurdle Rate. As<br />

reference portfolio we used a 25% stock <strong>an</strong>d 75% bond allocation. We identified<br />

a hurdle of 4.5%, i.e. when commodities produce <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>nualized return of 4.5% or<br />

more, they are allocated in the me<strong>an</strong> vari<strong>an</strong>ce framework. The modification of the<br />

efficient frontier when allocating commodities under the described <strong>as</strong>sumptions, is<br />

142 See [Best Grauer 1991] <strong>an</strong>d [Michaud 1998].<br />

155


6 <strong>Asset</strong> Allocation with Commodity Derivatives<br />

plotted in Figure 6.5.<br />

Figure 6.5: Efficient Frontier <strong>an</strong>d the Hurdle Rate<br />

The Minimum Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Portfolio of a traditional stock <strong>an</strong>d bond only portfolio h<strong>as</strong><br />

<strong>as</strong> reported in Figure 6.4 a stock allocation of 11.6% <strong>an</strong>d a bond allocation of 88.4%.<br />

Adding commodities yield to <strong>an</strong> improvement in two directions: choosing portfolio<br />

P C2<br />

at the efficient frontier with commodities would decre<strong>as</strong>e the taken risk around<br />

0.3% per <strong>an</strong>num while producing the same <strong>an</strong>nualized return of 4.48%. In the second<br />

possible c<strong>as</strong>e, choosing portfolio P C1 at the efficient frontier with commodities<br />

would incre<strong>as</strong>e the return around 0.2% per <strong>an</strong>num while taking the same risk of<br />

7.08%. This shows that especially the attractive st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation <strong>an</strong>d correlation<br />

structure commodity returns have to stock <strong>an</strong>d bond returns cause the need for<br />

allocating this <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d not the extraordinary returns generated during the<br />

l<strong>as</strong>t years. Nevertheless, 64% of the historical <strong>an</strong>nualized returns were bigger th<strong>an</strong><br />

the hurdle rate.<br />

Closing this section we c<strong>an</strong> state, that allocating commodities is essential for attractive<br />

risk <strong>an</strong>d return profiles especially in the low risk space.<br />

156


7 Conclusions<br />

As globalization <strong>an</strong>d computerization enabled multinational comp<strong>an</strong>ies to spread<br />

out their production pl<strong>an</strong>ts, the economic renaiss<strong>an</strong>ce of Asi<strong>an</strong> countries h<strong>as</strong> begun.<br />

To satisfy the growing need for infr<strong>as</strong>tructure, new buildings <strong>an</strong>d electrification,<br />

huge amounts of metals <strong>an</strong>d energy were pulled of global trade into the emerging<br />

markets. But the commodity producing industry w<strong>as</strong> not prepared <strong>an</strong>d scarcity<br />

let prices rise. This forced comp<strong>an</strong>y’s fin<strong>an</strong>cial m<strong>an</strong>agers to maintain their risk<br />

m<strong>an</strong>agement systems <strong>an</strong>d brought them to mind the need for fin<strong>an</strong>cial risk hedging<br />

products, investors were attracted by the extraordinary returns. The goal of this<br />

thesis h<strong>as</strong> been to highlight commodities <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s. Introductory, we gave <strong>an</strong><br />

overview of commodity markets which consists of three sub markets: energy, metals<br />

<strong>an</strong>d agriculture. Different characteristics <strong>an</strong>d fields of usage rose our awareness that<br />

there does not exist the ”average” commodity. The macroeconomic <strong>an</strong>d statistical<br />

facilities of the commodities under consideration differ essentially among each other<br />

resulting in diversification benefits when considering commodity b<strong>as</strong>kets.<br />

Nevertheless, commodities embody commonly a special facility: they are consumption<br />

goods. Therefore, the elementary fin<strong>an</strong>cial products to trade commodities c<strong>an</strong>not<br />

be valued following the same arbitrage arguments <strong>as</strong> they are used in traditional<br />

fin<strong>an</strong>cial derivatives pricing. Depending on the view that is taken of commodities<br />

<strong>as</strong> consumption goods or fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>sets, two different commodity futures pricing<br />

concepts were developed. If commodity futures are seen <strong>as</strong> derivatives written on a<br />

non-tradable reference figure, i.e. on the price of a consumption good, they should<br />

be valued b<strong>as</strong>ed on equilibrium <strong>as</strong>set pricing concepts. But if commodity futures<br />

are seen <strong>as</strong> derivatives written on <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set-like underlying, they should be valued<br />

b<strong>as</strong>ed on arbitrage related concepts. Risk Premium Models are equilibrium <strong>as</strong>set<br />

pricing concepts <strong>an</strong>d Convenience Yield Models are arbitrage related valuation concept.<br />

The convenience yield captures the additional value of the commodity <strong>as</strong><br />

consumption good on top of its value <strong>as</strong> tradable <strong>as</strong>set. Following [Markert 2005],<br />

we have shown that both valuation concepts are mutually consistent <strong>an</strong>d c<strong>an</strong> be<br />

derived from each other if the convenience yield is interpreted <strong>as</strong> the deviation of<br />

the commodity spot price from the value of the commodity <strong>as</strong> a pure fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>set.<br />

Especially for risk m<strong>an</strong>agement purposes, stoch<strong>as</strong>tic models were discussed to clone<br />

observed market prices. We introduced the most common one, two <strong>an</strong>d three factor<br />

models. Although latter ones fit best the term structure of commodity futures, two<br />

factor models are still more accepted in practice because they have the best trade<br />

off between fitting adv<strong>an</strong>tage <strong>an</strong>d computational costs.<br />

157


7 Conclusions<br />

The main focus of this thesis w<strong>as</strong> put on diversified commodity exposure represented<br />

by the DJ-AIGCI. The commodity index <strong>an</strong>alyzes of Section 4.2.7 <strong>an</strong>d Section 5.1.3<br />

identified it <strong>as</strong> bal<strong>an</strong>ced commodity investment b<strong>as</strong>ket using the attractive diversification<br />

effects offered by the heterogeneous commodity market. If commodities shall<br />

actually be allocated in a portfolio, total returns have to be considered. Their decomposition<br />

h<strong>as</strong> shown that they consist of spot, roll <strong>an</strong>d interest rate returns. Former<br />

represent the simple price ch<strong>an</strong>ges of the included commodities over time. But<br />

these are only tradable with futures contracts having fixed maturities. Therefore,<br />

long term orientation includes rolling the futures investment forward <strong>an</strong>d creating<br />

therewith the so-called roll returns. To trade futures contracts, only minimal c<strong>as</strong>h<br />

is required to serve margin calls. Therefore, fully collateralized futures portfolios<br />

are considered to produce additional interest rate return. Recall Figure 5.7 where<br />

the perform<strong>an</strong>ce of single return elements are shown <strong>an</strong>d the huge negative impact<br />

of roll returns on the total return.<br />

The ensuing statistical <strong>an</strong>alysis of the return components aimed to identify the<br />

behavior of commodity returns in the portfolio context. Normality of the DJ-AIGCI<br />

total return could not be proofed. The distribution is influenced by outliers <strong>an</strong>d<br />

peaked around the me<strong>an</strong>. Nevertheless, we found that correlations to the returns<br />

of the traditional <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses, stocks <strong>an</strong>d bonds, were slightly negative. Moreover,<br />

while stock <strong>an</strong>d bond returns show the well known leverage effect, i.e. returns<br />

<strong>an</strong>d their volatility are positively correlated, commodity returns exhibit a ”negative<br />

leverage effect”, i.e. returns <strong>an</strong>d their volatility are positively correlated. Price<br />

surges in commodity markets are caused by low inventories <strong>an</strong>d the fear of possible<br />

supply interruptions. This makes market particip<strong>an</strong>ts nervous <strong>an</strong>d it is expressed<br />

by higher volatility.<br />

To <strong>an</strong>swer the question if commodities indeed represent <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>s of its own,<br />

the me<strong>an</strong> vari<strong>an</strong>ce sp<strong>an</strong>ning h<strong>as</strong> to identify a statistical signific<strong>an</strong>t risk premium<br />

that c<strong>an</strong>not be explained by other already established <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses. We found a<br />

selected period that satisfies this condition. Moreover, a factor <strong>an</strong>alysis identified<br />

a single implicit risk factor driving commodity returns independently to stock <strong>an</strong>d<br />

bond returns. We deduce that commodities tend to be indeed a separate <strong>as</strong>set<br />

cl<strong>as</strong>s with its own risk <strong>an</strong>d return facilities that are different to the characteristics<br />

stock <strong>an</strong>d bond returns exhibit. Me<strong>an</strong> vari<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d hurdle rate <strong>an</strong>alyzes have shown<br />

that allocating commodities to a traditional stock <strong>an</strong>d bond portfolio yield to more<br />

attractive risk <strong>an</strong>d return profiles. This is re<strong>as</strong>oned by the risk <strong>an</strong>d correlation profile<br />

commodity returns have to stock <strong>an</strong>d bond returns <strong>an</strong>d not by the extraordinary<br />

commodity returns of the l<strong>as</strong>t years.<br />

158


Appendix


A Data Description<br />

Availability of data in commodity markets is rather scarce since the broad market<br />

development started only a couple of years ago <strong>an</strong>d different sources are spread out.<br />

Because commodities are traded in US dollar, all <strong>an</strong>alyzes are in US dollar.<br />

The first <strong>an</strong>alysis in Section 2.1 <strong>an</strong>d Appendix B yield to show the macroeconomic<br />

embedding of commodities <strong>as</strong> consumption good. The main data source w<strong>as</strong> the<br />

[The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005] which describes/publishes production, consumption<br />

<strong>an</strong>d price data. Over the long run, only spot price data were available.<br />

Therefore, the <strong>an</strong>alyzes are b<strong>as</strong>ed on this type of commodity return.<br />

Since the [The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005] w<strong>as</strong> not appropriate <strong>as</strong> data source,<br />

we used Bloomberg publishing ending stocks, production <strong>an</strong>d consumption data for<br />

selected commodities including different agricultures <strong>an</strong>d metals. Sometimes, the<br />

specific org<strong>an</strong>izations also provided these information, i.e. [USDA Livestock 2006].<br />

In Section 4.4 we used different futures prices to show how commodity time series<br />

are created. Data came from Bloomberg <strong>an</strong>d the ticker were composed following the<br />

lower methodology:<br />

NYMEX crude oil futures contract with ticker CLxy Comdty, whereby<br />

x ∈ (F (=J<strong>an</strong>), G (=Feb), H (=Mar), J (=Apr), K (=May), M (=Jun), N<br />

(=Jul), Q (=Aug), U (=Sep), V (=Oct), X (=Nov), Z (=Dec))<br />

representing the respective month starting with <strong>an</strong>d y ∈ (5, 6) representing the<br />

respective year<br />

LME copper futures contract with ticker LPxy Comdty, whereby<br />

x ∈ (F (=J<strong>an</strong>), G (=Feb), H (=Mar), J (=Apr), K (=May), M (=Jun), N<br />

(=Jul), Q (=Aug), U (=Sep), V (=Oct), X (=Nov), Z (=Dec))<br />

representing the respective month starting with <strong>an</strong>d y ∈ (5, 6) representing the<br />

respective year<br />

While there exists a huge amount of literature that examines time series constructed<br />

from futures prices, little is said about market indices <strong>an</strong>d their components. Therefore,<br />

our <strong>an</strong>alysis is focused on the indices in Section 5. In the first part, in<br />

Section 5.1 we aim to give a market overview <strong>an</strong>d compare single commodities,<br />

different commodity groups <strong>an</strong>d major market indices. The RICI is the youngest<br />

index with its introduction in August 1998. We set this time <strong>as</strong> a start to compare<br />

different indices over the same period of time. Taking into consideration that Gol-<br />

160


m<strong>an</strong> Sachs (GS) publishes <strong>as</strong> single provider a spot, excess <strong>an</strong>d total return for all<br />

its single <strong>an</strong>d sub indices, we used in this <strong>an</strong>alysis the GS single <strong>an</strong>d sub indices.<br />

The broad indices were calculated by their respective issuer. The Bloomberg tickers<br />

are <strong>as</strong> follows:<br />

GS G<strong>as</strong>oline Spot Return: GSCCHUSP Comdty<br />

GS G<strong>as</strong>oline Excess Return: GSCCHUER Comdty<br />

GS Natural G<strong>as</strong> Spot Return: G<strong>as</strong>GSCCNGSP Comdty<br />

GS Natural G<strong>as</strong> Excess Return: GSCCNGER Comdty<br />

GS Nickel Spot Return: GSCCIKSP Comdty<br />

GS Nickel Excess Return: GSCCIKER Comdty<br />

GS Zinc Spot Return: GSCCIZSP Comdty<br />

GS Zinc Excess Return: GSCCIZER Comdty<br />

GS Gold Spot Return: GSCCGCSP Comdty<br />

GS Gold Excess Return: GSCCGCER Comdty<br />

GS Corn Spot Return: GSCCCNSP Comdty<br />

GS Corn Excess Return: GSCCCNER Comdty<br />

GS Le<strong>an</strong> Hogs Spot Return: GSCCLHSP Comdty<br />

GS Le<strong>an</strong> Hogs Excess Return: GSCCLHER Comdty<br />

GS Sugar Spot Return: GSCCSBSP Comdty<br />

GS Sugar Excess Return: GSCCSBER Comdty<br />

GS Energy Spot Return: GSENSPOT Comdty<br />

GS Energy Excess Return: GSENER Comdty<br />

GS Industrial Metals Spot Return: GSINSPOT Comdty<br />

GS Industrial Metals Excess Return: GSINER Comdty<br />

GS Precious Metals Spot Return: GSPMSPOT Comdty<br />

GS Precious Metals Excess Return: GSPMER Comdty<br />

GS Agricultures Spot Return: GSCAGSPT Comdty<br />

GS Agricultures Excess Return: GSCAGER Comdty<br />

DJ-AIGCI Spot Return: AIGDJAIGSP Comdty<br />

DJ-AIGCI Excess Return: DJAIG Comdty<br />

161


A Data Description<br />

GSCI Spot Return: GSCISPOT Comdty<br />

GSCI Excess Return: GSCIER Comdty<br />

DBLCI Me<strong>an</strong> Reversion Excess Return: DBLCMMCL Comdty<br />

DBLCI Excess Return: DBLCIX Comdty<br />

RICI Excess Return: RICIGLER Comdty<br />

In Section 5.1.3 we decided to direct <strong>an</strong>y further <strong>an</strong>alyzes to the DJ-AIGCI. To<br />

cover the whole index history, we took data available <strong>as</strong> from 01.01.1991. Dow<br />

Jones (DJ) publishes excess return time series for its single <strong>an</strong>d sub indices. Only<br />

for the sub indices it publishes the spot return series, too. Therefore, the <strong>an</strong>alysis of<br />

the DJ-AIGCI return components w<strong>as</strong> confined. Nevertheless, the data for the factor<br />

<strong>an</strong>alysis in Section 5.1.3 <strong>an</strong>d the other <strong>an</strong>alyzes in Section 5.2 were downloaded from<br />

Bloomberg. The tickers are <strong>as</strong> follows:<br />

DJ-AIGCI Total Return: DJAIGTR Comdty<br />

DJ-AIGCI Spot Return: DJAIGSP Comdty<br />

DJ-AIGCI Excess Return: DJAIG Comdty<br />

DJ Energy Spot Return: DJAIGENSP Comdty<br />

DJ Energy Excess Return: DJAIGEN Comdty<br />

DJ Non - Energy Spot Return: DJAIGXESP Comdty<br />

DJ Non - Energy Excess Return: DJAIGXE Comdty<br />

DJ Industrial Metals Spot Return: DJAIGINSP Comdty<br />

DJ Industrial Metals Excess Return: DJAIGIN Comdty<br />

DJ Precious Metals Spot Return: DJAIGPRSP Comdty<br />

DJ Precious Metals Excess Return: DJAIGPR Comdty<br />

DJ Agricultures Spot Return: DJAIGAGSP Comdty<br />

DJ Agricultures Excess Return: DJAIGAG Comdty<br />

DJ Softs Spot Return: DJAIGSOSP Comdty<br />

DJ Softs Excess Return: DJAIGSO Comdty<br />

DJ Grains Spot Return: DJAIGGRSP Comdty<br />

DJ Grains Excess Return: DJAIGGR Comdty<br />

162


DJ Livestock Spot Return: DJAIGLISP Comdty<br />

DJ Livestock Excess Return: DJAIGLI Comdty<br />

Finally, in Section 6 we did some <strong>an</strong>alysis to embody commodity returns into the investment<br />

environment of the traditional <strong>as</strong>set cl<strong>as</strong>ses. For this purpose, the following<br />

data were used:<br />

DJ-AIGCI Total Return: DJAIGTR Comdty<br />

MSCI World USD: MSDUWI Index<br />

S&P500 Total Return: SPTR Index<br />

MSCI Europe: MSDUE15 Index<br />

J.P. Morg<strong>an</strong> Global Government Bond: JPMGGLBL Index<br />

J.P. Morg<strong>an</strong> Government Bond Index USA: JPMTUS Index<br />

J.P. Morg<strong>an</strong> Government Bond Index Europe: JPMGEURO Index<br />

OECD US Consumer Price Index, All Items: OEUSC009 Index<br />

All data were available in daily frequency, excluding the OECD US Consumer Price<br />

Index. It is given in a monthly frequency <strong>an</strong>d its ch<strong>an</strong>ging serves <strong>as</strong> me<strong>as</strong>ure of<br />

inflation.<br />

163


B Characteristics of Selected <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

B.1 Heating Oil<br />

About 25% of a barrel crude oil is used to produce heating oil. It is the second<br />

largest downstream product after g<strong>as</strong>oline refined from crude oil. Therefore, its<br />

price is highly correlated to crude oil prices. The consumer’s price for home heating<br />

oil generally includes up to 50% for crude oil, 11% refining costs, <strong>an</strong>d 39% marketing<br />

<strong>an</strong>d distribution costs. 143 Hence, there exists a trade off between heating <strong>an</strong>d crude<br />

oil prices. Dem<strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>d supply shifts caused by ch<strong>an</strong>ges in weather or refinery shutdowns<br />

result in higher heating oil prices <strong>an</strong>d effect the simult<strong>an</strong>eous rise of crude oil<br />

prices. Figure B.1 shows the similar price pattern over the l<strong>as</strong>t 40 years. The signific<strong>an</strong>t<br />

correlation coefficient between price ch<strong>an</strong>ges in the two price series is 0.66. 144<br />

Figure B.1: Dependence of Heating Oil Prices to Crude Oil Prices<br />

The processing margin which is earned when refiners buy crude oil <strong>an</strong>d refine it into<br />

heating oil <strong>an</strong>d g<strong>as</strong>oline is called ”crack spread”. It is common industry practice to<br />

react to the crack-spread ration 3-2-1, which involves selling 1 heating oil contract<br />

<strong>an</strong>d 2 g<strong>as</strong>oline futures contracts <strong>an</strong>d buying 3 crude oil contracts. As long <strong>as</strong> the<br />

crack spread is positive, it is profitable for refiners to buy crude oil <strong>an</strong>d refine it into<br />

the downstream products.<br />

Heating oil is mainly used for residential heating. In the US, there are still over<br />

7 million households which use it <strong>as</strong> primary heating fuel. The peak in dem<strong>an</strong>d<br />

143 See Energy Information Administration: st<strong>an</strong>d 2002.<br />

144 For this <strong>an</strong>alysis we took monthly c<strong>as</strong>h data of the [The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005]<br />

completed with Bloomberg data for 2005 <strong>an</strong>d 2006. We used monthly log returns <strong>as</strong> of<br />

Definition C.2. For the mathematical definition of Pearson correlation <strong>an</strong>d the related statistical<br />

test see Section 5.1.2.<br />

164


B.1 Heating Oil<br />

occurs during the winter months from October through March. Therefore, heating<br />

oil prices fluctuate se<strong>as</strong>onally. Prices incre<strong>as</strong>e during the filling months from March<br />

through October. Moreover, unexpected long <strong>an</strong>d hard winters c<strong>an</strong> cause further<br />

price rises due to pumping, pipeline or refinery bottlenecks within the period from<br />

December to March. In the l<strong>as</strong>t years dem<strong>an</strong>d in heating oil decre<strong>as</strong>ed in industrial<br />

countries. M<strong>an</strong>y households beg<strong>an</strong> to switch over to more convenient heating sources<br />

such <strong>as</strong> natural g<strong>as</strong>. Furthermore, there is a trend to mix traditional heating oil<br />

with natural sources. One idea to do so comes from the Purdue <strong>University</strong> (USA).<br />

They found a combination of 20% of soybe<strong>an</strong> oil <strong>an</strong>d 80% of conventional oil to be<br />

sufficient: The mix c<strong>an</strong> be used in conventional furnaces without altering existing<br />

equipment, is relatively e<strong>as</strong>y to produce <strong>an</strong>d produces no sulphur emissions.<br />

Thus, it appears that the high cost environment which we currently have in crude oil<br />

markets, applies to heating oil markets, too. Figure B.2 shows the prices of heating<br />

oil at the New York Merc<strong>an</strong>tile Exch<strong>an</strong>ge (NYMEX) for different future delivery<br />

dates <strong>as</strong> of July 2006. 145<br />

Figure B.2: Heating Oil Prices for Future Delivery<br />

First, we clearly discover the se<strong>as</strong>onality: prices are expected to fall towards the end<br />

of winter in March until the beginning of the filling se<strong>as</strong>on in July. In August 2007<br />

prices are expected to rise again. Second, the market expects heating oil to be<br />

more expensive in 2007 th<strong>an</strong> in 2006. Market particip<strong>an</strong>ts are willing to pay over<br />

5 US dollar more for heating oil that will be delivered in one <strong>an</strong>d a half year th<strong>an</strong><br />

for heating oil that will be delivered this winter.<br />

145 Data source: Bloomberg.<br />

165


B Characteristics of Selected <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

B.2 G<strong>as</strong>oline<br />

About 50% of a barrel crude oil is used to refine g<strong>as</strong>oline. In the USA, it accounts<br />

for about 17 % of the energy consumed yearly. 146 The primary use of g<strong>as</strong>oline is in<br />

automobiles <strong>an</strong>d light trucks. G<strong>as</strong>oline also fuels boats, recreational vehicles, various<br />

farm machines, <strong>an</strong>d other equipment. While g<strong>as</strong>oline is produced year-round,<br />

extra volumes are made for the summer driving se<strong>as</strong>on. There are three main grades<br />

of g<strong>as</strong>oline: regular, mid-grade, <strong>an</strong>d premium. Each grade h<strong>as</strong> a different oct<strong>an</strong>e<br />

level. 147 Oct<strong>an</strong>e is a me<strong>as</strong>ure of a g<strong>as</strong>oline’s ability to resist the pinging <strong>an</strong>d knocking<br />

noise of the engine. Additional refining steps are required to incre<strong>as</strong>e the oct<strong>an</strong>e<br />

which incre<strong>as</strong>e the retail price. Figure B.3 shows the price movements of g<strong>as</strong>oline<br />

compared to price movements with its major input factor crude oil. Ch<strong>an</strong>ges in both<br />

price series have a signific<strong>an</strong>t correlation coefficient of 0.67. 148 Both, heating oil <strong>an</strong>d<br />

g<strong>as</strong>oline, are priced with a refinery margin on top of the crude oil price. But in<br />

contr<strong>as</strong>t to heating oil, the g<strong>as</strong>oline peak time is in summer throughout the driving<br />

se<strong>as</strong>on. That is why these prices were more strongly submitted to the impacts of<br />

hurric<strong>an</strong>e Katrina in August 2005 th<strong>an</strong> the heating oil prices were.<br />

Figure B.3: Dependence of G<strong>as</strong>oline Prices on Crude Oil Prices<br />

In 2004, US retail prices of g<strong>as</strong>oline were summed up of 44% for crude oil, 27% for<br />

federal <strong>an</strong>d state taxes, 14% for distribution <strong>an</strong>d marketing <strong>an</strong>d 15% for refining<br />

costs <strong>an</strong>d profits. But in 2005, the US retail price of g<strong>as</strong>oline w<strong>as</strong> summed up<br />

146 See [The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005].<br />

147 87 (R+M)/2, 89 (R+M)/2 <strong>an</strong>d 93 (R+M)/2<br />

148 For this <strong>an</strong>alysis we took monthly c<strong>as</strong>h data of the [The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005]<br />

completed with Bloomberg data for 2005 <strong>an</strong>d 2006. We used monthly log returns <strong>as</strong> of<br />

Definition C.2. For the mathematical definition of Pearson correlation <strong>an</strong>d the related statistical<br />

test see Section 5.1.2.<br />

166


B.3 Gold<br />

of 47% for crude oil, 23% for federal <strong>an</strong>d state taxes, 12% for distribution <strong>an</strong>d<br />

marketing <strong>an</strong>d 18% for refining costs <strong>an</strong>d profits. 149 Both, crude oil prices <strong>an</strong>d<br />

margins rose. In real terms, the margin for refinery incre<strong>as</strong>ed around 10 US cents<br />

per gallon. This is typically for market environments with rising prices <strong>an</strong>d costs<br />

being p<strong>as</strong>sed on to customers.<br />

High costs <strong>an</strong>d environmental considerations have brought about reduced g<strong>as</strong>oline<br />

consumption over the course of years. In <strong>an</strong> attempt to improve air quality <strong>an</strong>d<br />

reduce harmful emissions from internal combustion engines, the US Congress p<strong>as</strong>sed<br />

the Cle<strong>an</strong> Air Act to m<strong>an</strong>date the addition of eth<strong>an</strong>ol to g<strong>as</strong>oline in 1990. The<br />

most common blend is E10, which contains 10% eth<strong>an</strong>ol <strong>an</strong>d 90% g<strong>as</strong>oline. Auto<br />

m<strong>an</strong>ufacturers have approved a fuel mixture that is produced by fermenting <strong>an</strong>d<br />

distilling crops such <strong>as</strong> corn, barley, wheat <strong>an</strong>d sugar. In Brazil, this proportion<br />

is much higher. Eth<strong>an</strong>ol accounts for 25% to 35% of the fuel. However, diesel<br />

<strong>an</strong>d bio fuels are getting more <strong>an</strong>d more popular in general. South America h<strong>as</strong><br />

by far the highest usage rates, but Europe <strong>an</strong>d North America are incre<strong>as</strong>ing their<br />

consumption, too. Nevertheless, we should also consider the growing dem<strong>an</strong>d of fuel<br />

<strong>an</strong>d g<strong>as</strong> from emerging Asi<strong>an</strong> markets. Taking into account that Asi<strong>an</strong> countries pay<br />

little attention to environmental issues, we may expect that these dem<strong>an</strong>ds continue<br />

to grow.<br />

B.3 Gold<br />

Since 1886 South Africa h<strong>as</strong> been the gold producing mecca of the world. At its<br />

peak production in 1970 South Africa contributed 79% of the world’s <strong>an</strong>nual supply.<br />

Its domin<strong>an</strong>t position h<strong>as</strong> w<strong>an</strong>ed in the l<strong>as</strong>t 30 years. Although it is still world’s<br />

largest producer, it just accounts for 20% of world production followed by the USA<br />

that accounts for around 10% of world production <strong>an</strong>d China, Russia <strong>an</strong>d Australia<br />

which all account for nearby 10% of world production. 150 South Africa’s diminishing<br />

production domin<strong>an</strong>ce is primarily due to v<strong>as</strong>t gold discoveries in North America<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Australia. Nevertheless, it continues to be unchallenged in the more import<strong>an</strong>t<br />

category of gold reserves. Moreover, recent m<strong>an</strong>power cuttings <strong>an</strong>d rationalizations<br />

resulted in major cost reductions throughout the South Afric<strong>an</strong> industry. Average<br />

production costs are now lower th<strong>an</strong> North Americ<strong>an</strong> mine ones. Especially during<br />

the years 1996 <strong>an</strong>d 2001 <strong>as</strong> the gold price w<strong>as</strong> very low South Africa’s currency, the<br />

R<strong>an</strong>d, depreciated to the US dollar over 50%. This dependency of the gold price<br />

149 See US Energy Information Administration (www.eia.doe.gov)<br />

150 See [UBS research 2005].<br />

167


B Characteristics of Selected <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

cried for economical diversification. Therefore, South Afric<strong>an</strong> producers shifted their<br />

focus into other precious metals like platinum which provided lucrative profits over<br />

the l<strong>as</strong>t years <strong>an</strong>d together with <strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>ing gold price the R<strong>an</strong>d re-appreciated.<br />

However, production extended in other parts of the world like Indonesia, Peru, Argentina<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the USA netting off South Africa’s production downturn. After a weak<br />

supply year 2004 that left a negative production consumption bal<strong>an</strong>ce of -135.8<br />

tonnes, the supply incre<strong>as</strong>ed in 2005 to 3.9 million tonnes <strong>an</strong>d could fill the bal<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

gab of the l<strong>as</strong>t year, although consumption incre<strong>as</strong>ed by around 7%. The gold<br />

dem<strong>an</strong>d is influenced by three independent factors: the investment, the industrial<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the hedging dem<strong>an</strong>d. First, geopolitical pressure <strong>an</strong>d wealth insur<strong>an</strong>ce caused<br />

by a weak dollar are the main drivers of the building up of gold reserves. Second,<br />

gold’s major industrial use is jewelery, dentistry <strong>an</strong>d electricity. The first two are<br />

mainly driven by st<strong>an</strong>dards of life. Gold jewelery h<strong>as</strong> its major use in the Middle<br />

E<strong>as</strong>t <strong>an</strong>d India, not only to dress women but also for religious purposes. With <strong>an</strong><br />

incre<strong>as</strong>e of wealth a dem<strong>an</strong>d surge c<strong>an</strong> be expected. Third, the hedging activities of<br />

gold producing comp<strong>an</strong>ies influence the gold price. In the first quarter of 2006 they<br />

held back 18% of mine production to sell it at higher prices. Figure B.4 shows the<br />

development of gold prices <strong>an</strong>d inventories between 1992 <strong>an</strong>d 2006. 151<br />

Figure B.4: Gold Inventories <strong>an</strong>d Prices<br />

Although inventories went up over the l<strong>as</strong>t years the gold price did <strong>as</strong> well. This<br />

reflects the currency facility of gold in international systems <strong>an</strong>d the negative US<br />

economy influences. The left scale is also used to reflect the values of the US dollar<br />

trade-weighted index to show the depreciation of the US dollar over time in contr<strong>as</strong>t<br />

to the appreciation of gold over the same time horizon.<br />

151 Data source: Bloomberg<br />

168


B.4 Aluminium<br />

B.4 Aluminium<br />

The silvery, lightweight metal called aluminium is extracted from <strong>an</strong> aluminium ore,<br />

also known <strong>as</strong> bauxite. The primary method is the electrolytic reduction. It w<strong>as</strong><br />

simult<strong>an</strong>eously discovered in 1886 by Charles Martin, USA, <strong>an</strong>d Paul L.T. Heroult,<br />

Fr<strong>an</strong>ce. 152 Bauxite c<strong>an</strong> be found in the tropical <strong>an</strong>d sub-tropical are<strong>as</strong> of Africa,<br />

India, South America <strong>an</strong>d Australia. By volume, aluminium weighs a third <strong>as</strong> steel<br />

<strong>an</strong>d h<strong>as</strong> therefore a high strength-to-weight ratio which makes it ideal for building<br />

<strong>an</strong>d construction what accounts for 22% of its total usage. Due to its resist<strong>an</strong>ce to<br />

corrosion in salt water, it is used in boat hulls <strong>an</strong>d various marine devices. Generally,<br />

26% of the aluminium consumption comes from tr<strong>an</strong>sportation business including<br />

auto mobiles <strong>an</strong>d air pl<strong>an</strong>ts. Another 22% of the total consumption are used in<br />

packing industry <strong>an</strong>d the rest is split to cooking materials, low-temperature nuclear<br />

reactors, machinery <strong>an</strong>d electricity.<br />

As mentioned by way of introduction, China is the heaviest user worldwide. Although<br />

24% of world production is done in Asia, Chinese have m<strong>as</strong>sive problems<br />

with old <strong>an</strong>d inefficient smelting pl<strong>an</strong>ts that hardly c<strong>an</strong> serve the internal dem<strong>an</strong>d.<br />

In 2005, Beijing introduced a 5% export tax to focus local producer on home markets.<br />

While other global operating comp<strong>an</strong>ies could buffer the trade drop from Far<br />

E<strong>as</strong>t over the short run, the situation became critical in 2006 <strong>as</strong> Figure B.5 shows.<br />

Inventories hit its 7 years low.<br />

Figure B.5: Aluminium Inventories <strong>an</strong>d Prices<br />

Huge requirements of energy for the electrolytic reduction process present the main<br />

problem in aluminium production. The production of one ton of aluminium requires<br />

152 See [The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005].<br />

169


B Characteristics of Selected <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

the same amount of energy <strong>as</strong> necessary to ensure the power supply of a detached<br />

family house throughout two years. Implicating, aluminium production costs are<br />

highly correlated to energy prices <strong>an</strong>d m<strong>an</strong>y aluminium smelting pl<strong>an</strong>ts are married<br />

to coal power pl<strong>an</strong>ts that are nowadays replaced by water or nuclear power pl<strong>an</strong>ts<br />

because of the high environmental pollution caused by burning coal to energy. The<br />

world’s biggest aluminium producer, Alcoa, is investing approximately one billion to<br />

build a smelting pl<strong>an</strong>t on Isl<strong>an</strong>d where volc<strong>an</strong>ic natural heat of the earth is cheap.<br />

The costs for the tr<strong>an</strong>sportation of raw material from Brazili<strong>an</strong> ore mines to Icel<strong>an</strong>d<br />

by sea <strong>an</strong>d the backhaul of pure aluminium to consumer markets in Europe, North<br />

America <strong>an</strong>d Asia do not net off the high energy costs somewhere else in the world<br />

making this complex logistic solution to the most cost efficient solution.<br />

Looking at today’s heaviest Aluminium consumer China, it h<strong>as</strong> still m<strong>as</strong>sive energy<br />

problems which limit the aluminium production of the country. In view of these<br />

problems, it c<strong>an</strong>not be <strong>as</strong>sumed that signific<strong>an</strong>t production exp<strong>an</strong>sion will decre<strong>as</strong>e<br />

prices for the short term.<br />

B.5 Copper<br />

The red coloured metal copper is the oldest metal in the history of m<strong>an</strong>kind. It is<br />

extracted <strong>an</strong>d worked up since 5,000 BC. Copper is, however, not only the oldest<br />

metal used by hum<strong>an</strong>s, but also one of the most widely used industrial metals.<br />

It is <strong>an</strong> excellent conductor, highly corrosion-resist<strong>an</strong>t <strong>an</strong>d ductile.<br />

Employment<br />

within electrical industry accounts about 41% of total copper usage with incre<strong>as</strong>ing<br />

tendency, owing to its better electric conductivity in comparison with aluminium.<br />

Therefore, it serves <strong>as</strong> a high-cl<strong>as</strong>s substitute for aluminium. Building construction<br />

is the single largest market accounting for 48% of total usage. 153 For better clearness:<br />

the average US home contains 200 kilograms of copper. Moreover, copper is biostatic<br />

which me<strong>an</strong>s that bacteria c<strong>an</strong>not grow on its surface. Therefore, it is used in airconditioning<br />

systems, on worktops <strong>an</strong>d doorknobs to prevent a spread of dise<strong>as</strong>es. 154<br />

The biggest copper output comes from Chile with 37% of world production. Alone<br />

8% of the world supply comes from the biggest BHB Billiton owned copper mine<br />

Escondido in the Atacama Desert. L<strong>as</strong>t year, the comp<strong>an</strong>y invested around 400<br />

million US dollar in a northerly located newly opened pit to meet the world copper<br />

dem<strong>an</strong>d. A r<strong>an</strong>ge of smaller suppliers are Australia, the USA, Russia, Peru <strong>an</strong>d Indonesia,<br />

all accounting between 6% <strong>an</strong>d 8% of world production. Figure B.6 shows<br />

153 See LME<br />

154 See [The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005].<br />

170


B.6 Lead<br />

the price <strong>an</strong>d inventory development over the l<strong>as</strong>t years.<br />

Figure B.6: Copper Inventories <strong>an</strong>d Prices<br />

The huge drop in inventories came in line with a huge price incre<strong>as</strong>e in 2003 which<br />

w<strong>as</strong> caused by <strong>an</strong> accident in the world’s third largest mine, the Indonesi<strong>an</strong> Gr<strong>as</strong>berg<br />

mine. A wall came down <strong>an</strong>d production w<strong>as</strong> discontinued for several month. But<br />

<strong>as</strong> it c<strong>an</strong> be seen, inventories grew again. Although, China c<strong>an</strong> only meet 4% of<br />

its dem<strong>an</strong>d, production is stable again <strong>an</strong>d higher th<strong>an</strong> consumption yielding into a<br />

refill of inventories. V<strong>as</strong>t copper reserves give re<strong>as</strong>on to <strong>as</strong>sume that copper prices<br />

will soon come down <strong>as</strong> it is the most over-priced metal.<br />

B.6 Lead<br />

Lead is a dense, toxic, gray metallic element. It is known for its stability <strong>an</strong>d is<br />

one of the oldest mined <strong>an</strong>d worked up metals. In the p<strong>as</strong>t, the metal w<strong>as</strong> used in<br />

decorative elements, windows, roofs <strong>an</strong>d pipelines routed in c<strong>as</strong>tles <strong>an</strong>d churches.<br />

Water pipelines in Rom<strong>an</strong> Aqueducts were made of lead. As scientists found out<br />

about the poisoning factor of lead, they speculated that lead poisoning could yield<br />

into the fall of the Rom<strong>an</strong> Empire. But these theories were later disproved.<br />

Today, lead is mainly used in electronics, that accounts for about 75% of its total<br />

usage. Batteries of nearly all tr<strong>an</strong>sportation vehicles contain lead. Moreover, lead<br />

is extensively used <strong>as</strong> a radiation shielding material owing to its high density <strong>an</strong>d<br />

nuclear properties. The steadily worldwide incre<strong>as</strong>ing dem<strong>an</strong>d for electricity <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the rediscovery of nuclear energy have caused a heavy dem<strong>an</strong>d for lead over the p<strong>as</strong>t<br />

years. Furthermore, lead is used <strong>as</strong> protection against radiation from computers,<br />

171


B Characteristics of Selected <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

television <strong>an</strong>d telecommunication. 155 Because production did not incre<strong>as</strong>e with dem<strong>an</strong>d,<br />

the stock of inventory fell over 75% between 2002 <strong>an</strong>d 2004. As a natural<br />

reaction, lead prices went up <strong>as</strong> Figure B.7 clearly shows.<br />

Figure B.7: Lead Inventories <strong>an</strong>d Prices<br />

The tremendous drop w<strong>as</strong> mainly driven by a production decline in Western countries.<br />

Caused by low lead prices during the 1990s comp<strong>an</strong>ies went out of business.<br />

But dem<strong>an</strong>d incre<strong>as</strong>ed steadily <strong>an</strong>d in 2005, there w<strong>as</strong> a world deficit in<br />

the production-consumption bal<strong>an</strong>ce sheet of 86,000 tonnes. The major producer<br />

is China with nearly one third of total world production <strong>an</strong>d high growth rates of<br />

10.7% in 2005. Since 2001, refined lead metal output in China h<strong>as</strong> doubled. The major<br />

lead producer is the Yug<strong>an</strong>g Lead Group which produced nearly 230,000 tonnes<br />

of refined lead in 2005, but on the other h<strong>an</strong>d, China also caused the tremendous<br />

dem<strong>an</strong>d incre<strong>as</strong>e for lead. L<strong>as</strong>t year, its dem<strong>an</strong>d incre<strong>as</strong>ed around 40%. Therewith,<br />

China overtook the USA <strong>as</strong> the world’s largest consumer of lead metal.<br />

Rising prices attracted new producers to jump into the market. For inst<strong>an</strong>ce, in<br />

Australia the Magell<strong>an</strong> mine w<strong>as</strong> opened in 2005, promising 70,000 tonnes output<br />

per year. But also Kazakhst<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d India, where Hindust<strong>an</strong> Zinc commissioned a<br />

new pl<strong>an</strong>t earlier this year, pushes production. The International Lead <strong>an</strong>d Zinc<br />

Study Group forec<strong>as</strong>ts that supply will exceed dem<strong>an</strong>d in 2006. This will give rising<br />

prises a rest.<br />

155 See [Rogers 2005].<br />

172


B.7 Nickel<br />

B.7 Nickel<br />

Nickel is a hard <strong>an</strong>d ductile metal that h<strong>as</strong> a silvery tinge. In 2005, 30% of<br />

world supply came from C<strong>an</strong>ada followed by Russia (23%), Australia (15%) <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Indonesia (10%). 156 It is a good conductor of heat <strong>an</strong>d electricity. It is used in<br />

rechargeable batteries <strong>an</strong>d in electric circuitry but only accounting for 8% of total<br />

consumption. Primary nickel c<strong>an</strong> resist corrosion <strong>an</strong>d maintains its physical <strong>an</strong>d<br />

mech<strong>an</strong>ical properties even if exposed to extreme temperatures. When these properties<br />

were recognized, the development of primary nickel beg<strong>an</strong>. It w<strong>as</strong> found that<br />

by combining primary nickel with steel, even in small qu<strong>an</strong>tities, the durability <strong>an</strong>d<br />

strength of steel incre<strong>as</strong>ed signific<strong>an</strong>tly <strong>as</strong> did its resist<strong>an</strong>ce to corrosion. Today,<br />

the production of stainless steel, a mixture of steel <strong>an</strong>d nickel, is the single largest<br />

consumer of primary nickel accounting for over 75% of total nickel consumption.<br />

Therefore, it is not <strong>as</strong>tonishing, that the run for nickel came in line with the run for<br />

steel mainly caused by China’s building <strong>an</strong>d construction boom. The price surge<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the drop in inventories c<strong>an</strong> be seen in Figure B.8 <strong>an</strong>d is highly dependent on<br />

China’s need for stainless steel <strong>an</strong>d other corrosion-resist<strong>an</strong>t alloys.<br />

Figure B.8: Nickel Inventories <strong>an</strong>d Prices<br />

The huge inventory loss through shrinkage w<strong>as</strong> mainly caused by production problems<br />

in three Australi<strong>an</strong> nickel projects (Murrin Murrin, Cawse <strong>an</strong>d Bulong). But<br />

this is all about to ch<strong>an</strong>ge. Moreover, the dem<strong>an</strong>d from China c<strong>an</strong> be expected to<br />

drop due to previous over-ordering. Nevertheless, inventories are low <strong>an</strong>d further<br />

supply interruptions or the inability to meet production pl<strong>an</strong>s will result in nervous<br />

price amplitudes. While Australia’s nickel miners are doing well, the nickel smelting<br />

156 See [UBS research 2005].<br />

173


B Characteristics of Selected <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

industry worldwide is operating at close to capacity. Furthermore, world production<br />

highly depends on C<strong>an</strong>ada but caused by strong winters the country remains a<br />

se<strong>as</strong>onal supplier.<br />

B.8 Zinc<br />

Zinc is a bluish-while metallic metal. It is never found in its pure state but rather<br />

in zinc oxide, zinc silicate, zinc carbonate, zinc sulphide, <strong>an</strong>d in different minerals.<br />

China with 22%, Australia with 14%, Peru with 15% <strong>an</strong>d C<strong>an</strong>ada with 11% of<br />

total world production are the major zinc suppliers. 157 Primarily zinc is utilized<br />

<strong>as</strong> a protective coating for other metals, such <strong>as</strong> iron <strong>an</strong>d steel, in a process called<br />

galv<strong>an</strong>izing <strong>an</strong>d in copper-zinc alloys. The galv<strong>an</strong>izing process incre<strong>as</strong>es corrosion<br />

resist<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d accounts for almost half its modern-day dem<strong>an</strong>d. Viewing business<br />

lines, 57% of total consume is pulled by building <strong>an</strong>d construction business. Another<br />

33% of total consumption are needed in tr<strong>an</strong>sportation <strong>an</strong>d machinery. Moreover,<br />

zinc is used <strong>as</strong> the negative electrode in dry cell (fl<strong>as</strong>hlight) batteries <strong>an</strong>d in round flat<br />

batteries which are normally used in watches, camer<strong>as</strong>, <strong>an</strong>d other electric devices.<br />

With 22% of world production China is the biggest producer worldwide but with<br />

a dem<strong>an</strong>d of 20% this nearly nets off. Chinese net imports of refined zinc metal<br />

totalled 265,000 tonnes in 2005. The primary source of imported material continued<br />

to be Kazakhst<strong>an</strong>, although subst<strong>an</strong>tial qu<strong>an</strong>tities were also sourced from Australia.<br />

As is c<strong>an</strong> be seen in Figure B.9 zinc inventories have decre<strong>as</strong>ed over the l<strong>as</strong>t three<br />

years. Since 2004 zinc metal production h<strong>as</strong> exceeded dem<strong>an</strong>d. In the Western<br />

World there w<strong>as</strong> a shortfall of 319,000 tonnes <strong>an</strong>d globally of 317,000 tonnes in<br />

2005. 158 Although the USA decre<strong>as</strong>ed its dem<strong>an</strong>d, the growth in Chinese dem<strong>an</strong>d<br />

exceeded the drop <strong>an</strong>d caused the negative ending stocks.resulting in falling inventories<br />

<strong>as</strong> Figure B.9 shows.<br />

Although, mine output is stable <strong>an</strong>d growing with rates around 4%, the International<br />

Lead <strong>an</strong>d Zinc Study Group forec<strong>as</strong>ts <strong>an</strong> ending stock deficit of 437,000 tonnes in<br />

2006. The global usage of refined zinc metal will incre<strong>as</strong>e again, strongest in Asia<br />

where dem<strong>an</strong>d is forec<strong>as</strong>t to rise by 7.3% in China, 9.1% in India, 4.5% in Jap<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d<br />

4.4% in the Republic of Korea. This might put prices furthermore under pressure.<br />

157 See [UBS research 2005].<br />

158 See The International Lead <strong>an</strong>d Zinc Study Group.<br />

174


B.9 Sugar<br />

Figure B.9: Zinc Inventories <strong>an</strong>d Prices<br />

B.9 Sugar<br />

”Sugar makes life sweet”, <strong>an</strong> advertising slog<strong>an</strong> that points out the import<strong>an</strong>ce of<br />

this commodity for everybody. The brown <strong>an</strong>d white crystalline fabric is a subst<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

produced from sugar c<strong>an</strong>e or sugar beets. Sugar c<strong>an</strong>e w<strong>as</strong> originally known in tropical<br />

regions of the world. People chew pieces of the stalk to extract the sweet t<strong>as</strong>te. In<br />

India, China <strong>an</strong>d the Middle E<strong>as</strong>t the first refinery methodologies were introduced.<br />

Since 1800, sugar is produced industrially <strong>an</strong>d traded all over the world.<br />

Today, sugar c<strong>an</strong>e or sugar beets are pl<strong>an</strong>ted in over 100 countries worldwide. Sugar<br />

c<strong>an</strong>e counts for 70% of world production <strong>an</strong>d sugar beets count for the remainder.<br />

The trend h<strong>as</strong> been that production of sugar from c<strong>an</strong>e is relatively incre<strong>as</strong>ing to<br />

that produced from beets because sugar c<strong>an</strong>e is a perennial, while sugar beet is <strong>an</strong><br />

<strong>an</strong>nual pl<strong>an</strong>t. Due to the longer production cycle, sugar c<strong>an</strong>e production is generally<br />

more resist<strong>an</strong>t to ch<strong>an</strong>ges in price th<strong>an</strong> sugar beet production.<br />

The worldwide biggest producer is Brazil with around 20% of the world supply.<br />

In the l<strong>as</strong>t 10 years it incre<strong>as</strong>ed its production around 9% <strong>an</strong>nually. Because of<br />

low sugar prices between 1999 <strong>an</strong>d 2002 m<strong>an</strong>y countries like Thail<strong>an</strong>d, Pakist<strong>an</strong><br />

<strong>an</strong>d India have reduced their production. The Brazili<strong>an</strong> production incre<strong>as</strong>e could<br />

therefore just net of their reductions what caused inventories to fall <strong>an</strong>d the prices<br />

to rise. Figure B.10 shows the historical development of sugar production, consumption,<br />

inventories <strong>an</strong>d c<strong>as</strong>h prices. Higher volatility of production in comparison to<br />

volatility of consumption indicates that supply is the more susceptible component<br />

affected e.g. by unexpected weather conditions.<br />

Taking a look into futures prices of futures maturing in 2008 we notice that prices<br />

will remain at a high level what is due to the growing dem<strong>an</strong>d for bio fuels <strong>as</strong> a<br />

175


B Characteristics of Selected <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

Figure B.10: Sugar Price, Stock of Inventory, Production <strong>an</strong>d Consumption<br />

substitute for g<strong>as</strong>oline. Eth<strong>an</strong>ol refined from sugar is <strong>an</strong> ingredient to produce these<br />

alternative fuels. Brazil is the biggest user worldwide with <strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>ing dem<strong>an</strong>d<br />

for eth<strong>an</strong>ol fuel caused by <strong>an</strong> enthusi<strong>as</strong>tic reception by consumers of the flex-fuel<br />

vehicle. Production reached its all time high with 17.4 billion liters. In the USA, 95<br />

eth<strong>an</strong>ol refineries were in production in 2005, 14 beg<strong>an</strong> production, 30 were under<br />

construction, 10 were exp<strong>an</strong>ded <strong>an</strong>d the industry produced a record of 15.1 billion<br />

litres. 159 Implementation of the Renewable Fuel’s st<strong>an</strong>dard (RFS) is in process <strong>an</strong>d<br />

will ensure a strong, long term future for bio fuel. Europe is focused to establish<br />

bio fuel st<strong>an</strong>dards, too, but m<strong>an</strong>y countries are lagging behind. Nevertheless, in<br />

November 2005 the ”biom<strong>as</strong>s action pl<strong>an</strong>” w<strong>as</strong> p<strong>as</strong>sed including bio fuel targets <strong>an</strong>d<br />

<strong>as</strong>sessments of how bio fuel incentives fit in with reforms of the Common Agriculture<br />

Policy.<br />

Closing this section, we shall take a look at Far E<strong>as</strong>t. China is with 8% of world<br />

supply the third biggest producer but with 9% of world usage the second biggest<br />

consumer. India is with 10% of world supply the second biggest producer but with<br />

14% of world usage the biggest consumer. According to <strong>an</strong> ISO study of May 2006,<br />

China is likely to incre<strong>as</strong>e its consumption about one third of today’s usage caused<br />

by growing st<strong>an</strong>dard of living. We <strong>as</strong>sume that this will be similar in India. When<br />

it comes to food, we should keep in mind that around 3 billion people are hungry<br />

to enter western st<strong>an</strong>dards.<br />

159 See International Sugar Org<strong>an</strong>ization (ISO) ”Quarterly Reports”<br />

176


B.10 Coffee<br />

B.10 Coffee<br />

The black hot drink made out of coffee powder w<strong>as</strong> first popular in Arabi<strong>an</strong> countries<br />

in the 13th century. Histori<strong>an</strong>s <strong>as</strong>cribe its popularity to the b<strong>an</strong> of alcohol in these<br />

countries. The secret of pl<strong>an</strong>ting coffee trees <strong>an</strong>d ro<strong>as</strong>ting coffee be<strong>an</strong>s, which are<br />

finally cr<strong>as</strong>hed to coffee powder, w<strong>as</strong> strictly kept. English men were the first who<br />

cultivated coffee drinking in Europe in the 17th century. But caused by tree illnesses<br />

in the colonial pl<strong>an</strong>ts they switched over to tea. Today, the USA is the biggest<br />

consumer with around 21 million bags in 2005, followed by Germ<strong>an</strong>y with around 8<br />

million bags in 2005 <strong>an</strong>d Italy <strong>an</strong>d Fr<strong>an</strong>ce, both with around 5 million bags in 2005.<br />

The evergreen tropical shrub c<strong>an</strong> grow up to 3.5 meters <strong>an</strong>d it takes around 9<br />

month to ripe the coffee be<strong>an</strong>s. Generally there are two br<strong>an</strong>ds of coffee: Arabica<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Robusta.<br />

The most widely produced coffee is Arabica, which makes up about 70% of total<br />

worldwide production with Brazil <strong>an</strong>d Colombia being the major producers. Robusta<br />

is a more resist<strong>an</strong>t br<strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>d c<strong>an</strong> be pl<strong>an</strong>ted in a soil which is not suitable<br />

to grow Arabica. The main producers are Indonesia, Vietnam <strong>an</strong>d West Africa.<br />

South America accounts generally for around two thirds of world production <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Africa <strong>an</strong>d Asia share nearby equally the other third. Figure B.11 shows the price<br />

development of Arabica coffee traded at the New York Board of Trade (NYBT) over<br />

the l<strong>as</strong>t 60 years.<br />

Figure B.11: Coffee Price<br />

There were two major coffee crises during the l<strong>as</strong>t 25 years but the latter between<br />

1999 <strong>an</strong>d 2003 w<strong>as</strong> the worst one: prices dropped around 50 cents per pound in 2002.<br />

Although retail prices remained stable <strong>an</strong>d industry’s income exceeded 70 billion US<br />

177


B Characteristics of Selected <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

dollar in 2005, the tiny fraction of 5.5 billion US dollar went to the producing countries<br />

where 125 million people are dependent on coffee with their livelihood. Prices<br />

fell down that hardly that m<strong>an</strong>y producers went out of business <strong>an</strong>d tried either to<br />

ch<strong>an</strong>ge to crop or left the country. For inst<strong>an</strong>ce, the USA had severe problems with<br />

illegal immigr<strong>an</strong>ts from South America in this time, <strong>an</strong>d in Colombia <strong>an</strong>d Guatemala<br />

there w<strong>as</strong> a strong incre<strong>as</strong>e in coca pl<strong>an</strong>ting. The price collapse w<strong>as</strong> caused by over<br />

production: extraordinary harvests in Brazil <strong>an</strong>d a v<strong>as</strong>t extension of production in<br />

Vietnam by nearly doubling its output from around 7 million bags in 1998 to around<br />

12 million bags in 1999 <strong>an</strong>d becoming the world’s major producer of Robusta <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the second largest producer of coffee worldwide behind Brazil. Figure B.12 shows<br />

the incre<strong>as</strong>e in inventory <strong>an</strong>d the related price decre<strong>as</strong>e.<br />

Figure B.12: Coffee Price <strong>an</strong>d Stock of Inventory<br />

The years of coffee recession caused a production decline over the l<strong>as</strong>t 3 years from<br />

121 million bags in 2002 to 106 million bags in 2005. On the other h<strong>an</strong>d, consumption<br />

developed const<strong>an</strong>tly with <strong>an</strong>nual growth rates of 2% over the same period. As<br />

a result, inventories started to decre<strong>as</strong>e <strong>an</strong>d prices incre<strong>as</strong>ed again. Because negative<br />

price shocks generally resonate for a long time, it c<strong>an</strong>not be expected that production<br />

will boom soon <strong>an</strong>d it might be that coffee markets finally run into a period of<br />

stable prices.<br />

B.11 Soybe<strong>an</strong> Complex<br />

The soybe<strong>an</strong> is a member of the oilseed family <strong>an</strong>d is <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>cient food crop from<br />

China, Jap<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d Korea. There it h<strong>as</strong> been known for more th<strong>an</strong> 4,500 years. The<br />

pl<strong>an</strong>t w<strong>as</strong> introduced to its currently biggest producer, the USA, in the early 1800s.<br />

178


B.11 Soybe<strong>an</strong> Complex<br />

Today, soybe<strong>an</strong>s are the second largest crop produced in the USA behind corn. The<br />

key value of soybe<strong>an</strong>s lies in the relatively high protein content, its similarity to<br />

corn <strong>an</strong>d its remarkable resistibility which brought it the name ”miracle pl<strong>an</strong>t”.<br />

The be<strong>an</strong>s are pl<strong>an</strong>ted in spring, usually in April <strong>an</strong>d May, but at the latest until<br />

early July. Late crop runs the risk of being caught by <strong>an</strong> early frost in fall <strong>an</strong>d<br />

may have difficulties flowering <strong>an</strong>d setting pods in August. The seeds are harvested<br />

100 - 150 days later in autumn.<br />

Soybe<strong>an</strong>s are used to produce a wide variety of food products. Its high protein<br />

content makes it <strong>an</strong> excellent source of protein without m<strong>an</strong>y of the negative factors<br />

of <strong>an</strong>imal meat. Popular soy-b<strong>as</strong>ed food products include whole soybe<strong>an</strong>s ro<strong>as</strong>ted<br />

for snacks or used in sauces, soy oil for cooking <strong>an</strong>d baking, soy protein concentrates<br />

which contain up to 92% protein, soy milk, yogurt <strong>an</strong>d cheese, tofu, tofu products<br />

<strong>an</strong>d meat alternatives such <strong>as</strong> hamburger <strong>an</strong>d sausages.<br />

When it comes to exch<strong>an</strong>ge tradable soybe<strong>an</strong> products, the market talks about the<br />

”Soybe<strong>an</strong> Complex” including soybe<strong>an</strong>s, soybe<strong>an</strong> meal <strong>an</strong>d soybe<strong>an</strong> oil whereby latter<br />

both are produced by crushing soybe<strong>an</strong>s. Typically, about 19% of a soybe<strong>an</strong>’s<br />

weight c<strong>an</strong> be extracted <strong>as</strong> crude soybe<strong>an</strong> oil.<br />

The oil content of a be<strong>an</strong> correlates<br />

directly with the temperatures <strong>an</strong>d amount of sunshine during the soybe<strong>an</strong><br />

pod - filling period. Soy oil is cholesterol-free <strong>an</strong>d high on polyunsaturated fat. Of<br />

the edible vegetable oils, soy oil is the world’s largest at about 32%, followed by palm<br />

oil <strong>an</strong>d rapeseed oil. An import<strong>an</strong>t product extracted from soybe<strong>an</strong> oil is lecithin<br />

which is used in m<strong>an</strong>y food preparations <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> emulsifier.<br />

Soybe<strong>an</strong> meal makes<br />

up about 35% of the weight of raw soybe<strong>an</strong>s. If the seeds are of particularly good<br />

quality, then the processor c<strong>an</strong> get more meal by including more hulls in the meal<br />

while still meeting the 48% protein minimum needed to meet exch<strong>an</strong>ges’ quality<br />

requirements. Generally, soybe<strong>an</strong> meal is used for <strong>an</strong>imal feed for poultry, hogs <strong>an</strong>d<br />

cattle. It accounts for about two thirds of the world’s high protein <strong>an</strong>imal feed. Its<br />

main competitor is corn but owing to its higher protein content it exhibits a price<br />

premium. 160<br />

Because soybe<strong>an</strong> oil <strong>an</strong>d meal are downstream products of soybe<strong>an</strong>s, they are traded<br />

at a premium called ”crush spread”, <strong>an</strong>d price series are highly correlated with<br />

signific<strong>an</strong>t coefficients of 0.82 between soybe<strong>an</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d soybe<strong>an</strong> meal <strong>an</strong>d 0.65 between<br />

soybe<strong>an</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d soybe<strong>an</strong> oil. 161<br />

It is a very popular agricultural spread <strong>an</strong>d traded<br />

160 See [The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005].<br />

161 For the <strong>an</strong>alysis we took monthly c<strong>as</strong>h data since 1970 of the<br />

[The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005] completed with Bloomberg data for 2005 <strong>an</strong>d<br />

179


B Characteristics of Selected <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

by the simult<strong>an</strong>eous purch<strong>as</strong>e or sale of soybe<strong>an</strong> futures <strong>an</strong>d the sale or purch<strong>as</strong>e of<br />

soybe<strong>an</strong> oil <strong>an</strong>d soybe<strong>an</strong> meal futures. Trading the spread between oil <strong>an</strong>d meal is<br />

also possible: if meal dem<strong>an</strong>d is high <strong>an</strong>d oil dem<strong>an</strong>d is not, all the same processors<br />

proceed crushing <strong>an</strong>d allow oil stocks to build up in <strong>an</strong>ticipation of future dem<strong>an</strong>d.<br />

Bedding on the spread’s ch<strong>an</strong>ges c<strong>an</strong> therefore pay off. 162<br />

Prior to the 1970s, the USA had a monopoly on soybe<strong>an</strong>s. Caused by a feed shortage<br />

in protein, the secret of pl<strong>an</strong>ting w<strong>as</strong> p<strong>as</strong>sed on to Brazil <strong>an</strong>d Argentina. Both countries<br />

boosted their production extraordinarily: while the USA accounted for around<br />

50% of world production <strong>an</strong>d 73% of world exports in 1995, their share reduced to<br />

37% of world production <strong>an</strong>d 42% of world exports in 2006. The lost market shares<br />

went to Argentina <strong>an</strong>d Brazil. Especially Brazil became the major competitor of<br />

the USA: in 2005 they supplied around 39% of world soybe<strong>an</strong> trade in comparison<br />

to the USA what accounted for around 38% of world soybe<strong>an</strong> trade. This year the<br />

picture h<strong>as</strong> ch<strong>an</strong>ged dramatically: only 60% of this year’s Brazili<strong>an</strong> soybe<strong>an</strong> crop<br />

h<strong>as</strong> been sold, yet. In comparison to the 5-year average, this is a sales drop of 10%.<br />

It originates from the strong Brazili<strong>an</strong> Real compared to the US dollar. Where<strong>as</strong> in<br />

2004, it w<strong>as</strong> possible to get over three Real for one US dollar, it is today merely 2.1.<br />

This makes Brazili<strong>an</strong> products expensive in comparison to USA ones yielding to a<br />

falling export rate to 36% for Brazil <strong>an</strong>d a rising export rate of 42% for the USA<br />

in 2006. Figure B.13 shows the global development of soybe<strong>an</strong> inventory, production<br />

<strong>an</strong>d consumption over the l<strong>as</strong>t centuries. 163<br />

Soybe<strong>an</strong> inventory h<strong>as</strong> grown since the South Americ<strong>an</strong> countries have pushed for<br />

the market. The biggest importer worldwide is China, followed by Europe. While<br />

Europe imported around 45% of world supply in 1995, the country of Far E<strong>as</strong>t<br />

just accounted for 2.5% of world supply. In 2006 China’s imports have grown to<br />

45% of world supply, while Europe’s imports fall back to 20% of world supply. The<br />

strong incre<strong>as</strong>e is caused by rising meat consumption in China, a focus to industrial<br />

products <strong>an</strong>d a migration into cities. For the coming years, a further consumption<br />

incre<strong>as</strong>e c<strong>an</strong> be expected because the st<strong>an</strong>dard of living will incre<strong>as</strong>e <strong>an</strong>d therewith<br />

meat consumption.<br />

2006. We used monthly log returns <strong>as</strong> of Definition C.2. For the mathematical definition of<br />

Pearson correlation <strong>an</strong>d the related statistical test see Section 5.1.2.<br />

162 Because dem<strong>an</strong>d for oil <strong>an</strong>d meal is driven by different factors their price series among each<br />

other are less correlated th<strong>an</strong> their price series to soybe<strong>an</strong> prices are. The signific<strong>an</strong>t correlation<br />

coefficient is 0.36.<br />

163 See [USDA Oilseeds 2006], Bloomberg <strong>an</strong>d [The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005].<br />

180


B.12 Le<strong>an</strong> Hogs<br />

Figure B.13: Soybe<strong>an</strong> Price, Stock of Inventory, Production <strong>an</strong>d Consumption<br />

B.12 Le<strong>an</strong> Hogs<br />

Hogs are generally bred twice a year in a continuous cycle designed to provide a<br />

steady flow of production. The gestation period for hogs is 3 <strong>an</strong>d a half months<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the average litter size is 9 pigs. After 3 - 4 weeks the pigs are taken away from<br />

their mother <strong>an</strong>d then fed to maximize weight gain. The food consists primarily of<br />

grains such <strong>as</strong> corn, barley, wheat <strong>an</strong>d soybe<strong>an</strong>s for protein. Hogs typically gain 3.1<br />

pounds per pound feed. The time until slaughter is usually 6 month when the pigs<br />

have reached a weight of around 190 pounds. 164<br />

The biggest producer worldwide is China with around 53% of share of total world<br />

production. Thus, small ch<strong>an</strong>ges in Chinese production <strong>an</strong>d consumption have a<br />

signific<strong>an</strong>t impact to the world-hog markets. From 2005 to 2006 China incre<strong>as</strong>ed its<br />

production by almost 5%. This development may subst<strong>an</strong>tiated through m<strong>an</strong>ifold<br />

re<strong>as</strong>ons: pork’s’ popularity in Chinese diet, continued higher disposable incomes,<br />

strong profitability in pork business, incre<strong>as</strong>ed investment in the sectors’ operations<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the substitution of poultry due to the bird flue. The influence of latter one<br />

c<strong>an</strong> clearly be seen in Figure B.14 in a huge price incre<strong>as</strong>e of pork in 2003, the<br />

year <strong>as</strong> bird flue w<strong>as</strong> first mentioned in the media. Nevertheless, China’s per capita<br />

consumption is around 39 kilograms per person. This is 5 kilograms less th<strong>an</strong> in<br />

Europe, the world’s second largest pork consumer in 2006. 165<br />

If China w<strong>an</strong>ts to<br />

reach Europe<strong>an</strong> st<strong>an</strong>dards they will have to produce 12 million tons more pork per<br />

year i.e. they will have to incre<strong>as</strong>e their production around 25% <strong>an</strong>d to cut off their<br />

exports.<br />

164 See [The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005].<br />

165 Surprisingly, Hong Kong is the world’s biggest pork user. People there consume around<br />

65 kilograms per year. See [USDA Livestock 2006]<br />

181


B Characteristics of Selected <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

Figure B.14: Le<strong>an</strong> Hogs Price, Stock of Inventory, Production <strong>an</strong>d Consumption<br />

Europe is the world’s largest exporter accounting for around 30% of world trade<br />

<strong>an</strong>d second largest producer with 21.5 million kilograms in 2006. No wonder that<br />

the outbreak of swine fever at the end of the 1990s had tremendous impacts on<br />

world pork prices <strong>as</strong> it c<strong>an</strong> be seen in Figure B.14. Somebody might remember the<br />

headlines <strong>as</strong> the Netherl<strong>an</strong>ds had to kill more th<strong>an</strong> 12 million pigs in one go those<br />

days.<br />

Nowadays, EU business is pushed by the substitution of poultry <strong>an</strong>d the cheap food<br />

costs in the new member countries. Jap<strong>an</strong> w<strong>as</strong> one of the biggest addresses for<br />

Europe<strong>an</strong> pork. But prices c<strong>an</strong>’t st<strong>an</strong>d USA prices. It incre<strong>as</strong>ed its exports by<br />

around 80% since 2001. While its exports accounted for 21% of total world supply<br />

in 2001 it accounts know for 25% of total world supply.<br />

Since 2004, the so-called ”hog crush” <strong>an</strong>d ”cattle crush” c<strong>an</strong> be traded what w<strong>as</strong><br />

enabled by a bilateral engagement of the Chicago Merc<strong>an</strong>tile Exch<strong>an</strong>ge (CME) <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the Chicago Board of Trade (CBOT). The hogs spread is constructed by buying<br />

one corn futures contract <strong>an</strong>d selling two le<strong>an</strong> hog futures contracts because one<br />

corn contract contains 5000 bushels or 2800 pounds, which is almost enough corn<br />

to raise 400 pigs, the equivalent to 2 hog futures contracts. The cattle spread is<br />

constructed by buying one corn <strong>an</strong>d one feeder cattle contract <strong>an</strong>d selling two live<br />

cattle contracts. These new products developed originally out of the producers<br />

hedging point of few enable speculators to ”feed” hogs or cattle ”on paper”. 166<br />

166 See [Crush Spread 2006].<br />

182


C Mathematical Preliminaries<br />

C.1 Statistical B<strong>as</strong>ics<br />

In this section we will give some b<strong>as</strong>ic definitions of used terminology. Generally,<br />

we tried to define the relev<strong>an</strong>t term during the description of the respective <strong>an</strong>alysis<br />

for better connection of theory <strong>an</strong>d praxis.<br />

Our general starting point of all <strong>an</strong>alysis are the price series available in Bloomberg.<br />

Let P t denote the price of <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set at time t. From this we c<strong>an</strong> calculate two types<br />

of return, a discrete <strong>an</strong>d continuous one:<br />

Definition C.1 Discrete Return<br />

The one period simple or discrete return is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

R t = P t − P t−1<br />

P t−1<br />

Definition C.2 Continuous Compounding Return<br />

The one period continuous compounding or log return is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

( )<br />

Pt<br />

r t = ln<br />

P t−1<br />

(C.1)<br />

(C.2)<br />

The following equation links both return definitions:<br />

R t = e rt − 1 or r t = ln(R t + 1) (C.3)<br />

In general, the difference between continuous <strong>an</strong>d simple returns is very small, especially<br />

for short time scales like ticks, days or months. This c<strong>an</strong> be seen with the<br />

Taylor series:<br />

R t<br />

(C.3)<br />

{}}{<br />

= e rt − 1 =<br />

=<br />

∞∑<br />

i=1<br />

∞∑<br />

i=0<br />

r i t<br />

i! = r t +<br />

r i t<br />

i! − 1<br />

∞∑ rt<br />

i<br />

i!<br />

i=2<br />

(C.4)<br />

Equation (C.4) shows that the two return definitions just differentiate from each<br />

other over higher order terms. For values around zero, they have little weight causing<br />

183


C Mathematical Preliminaries<br />

only small differences between the two return definitions. 167<br />

A major facility of log returns is its time additivity. Following Definition C.2, with<br />

0 ≤ s < t ≤ T , we have:<br />

r 0→t = ln<br />

( ) P (t)<br />

= ln<br />

P (0)<br />

( )<br />

P (t) ∗ P (s)<br />

= ln<br />

P (0) ∗ P (s)<br />

( ) P (s)<br />

+ ln<br />

P (0)<br />

( ) P (t)<br />

= r 0→s + r s→t<br />

P (s)<br />

(C.5)<br />

For continuous compounding returns the recalculation to prices is given <strong>as</strong>:<br />

Definition C.3 Price Series<br />

Let r t denote the log return of <strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>set at time t. The price of the <strong>as</strong>set is then<br />

defined <strong>as</strong>: P (t) = P (t − 1) ∗ e rt .<br />

The available information are mathematically embodied in the σ-Algebra.<br />

Definition C.4 σ-Algebra<br />

A system F of subsets of the sample space Ω is called σ-Algebra if it h<strong>as</strong> the following<br />

features:<br />

1. ∅ ∈ F<br />

2. A ∈ F ⇒ A c ∈ F<br />

3. A 1 , A 2 , A 3 . . . ∈ F ⇒ ⋃ n<br />

i=1 A i ∈ F<br />

The σ-Algebra of all open intervals of R is called the Borel-σ-Algebra.<br />

An import<strong>an</strong>t example of such a sigma-Algebra is he so-called Borel sigma-Algebra<br />

B(R k ),with R denoting the real numbers, that is the smallest sigma-Algebra containing<br />

all open sets in R k .<br />

Definition C.5 Probability M<strong>as</strong>s<br />

Let F be a σ-Algebra in Ω. A probability m<strong>as</strong>s is a function Q : F → R with the<br />

following features:<br />

1. Q(A) ≥ 0 for all A ∈ F<br />

2. Q(Ω) = 1<br />

3. for all A i ∈ F, i ∈ N with A i<br />

⋂<br />

Aj = ∅ for all i, j ∈ N with i ≠ j is:<br />

( ∞<br />

) (<br />

∑<br />

∞<br />

)<br />

⋃<br />

Q A i ≡ Q A i =<br />

i=1<br />

i=1<br />

167 Compare [Dorfleitner 2002].<br />

∞∑<br />

Q(A i )<br />

i=1<br />

(C.6)<br />

184


C.1 Statistical B<strong>as</strong>ics<br />

The triple (Ω, F, Q) is called probability space.<br />

A r<strong>an</strong>dom variable is a mathematical function that maps outcomes of r<strong>an</strong>dom experiments<br />

to numbers.<br />

Definition C.6 R<strong>an</strong>dom Variable<br />

Let (Ω, F, Q) be a probability space <strong>an</strong>d let B denote the Borel-σ-Algebra.<br />

function R : Ω ↦→ R with R −1 (B) ∈ F for all B ∈ B is called r<strong>an</strong>dom variable.<br />

The<br />

A reel number R(ω) = r, ω ∈ Ω is called the realization of R.<br />

Definition C.7 Distribution<br />

The probability m<strong>as</strong>s Q R on (R, B 1 ) defined by Q R (B) ≡ Q(R −1 (B)) is called<br />

distribution of R.<br />

A probability density function c<strong>an</strong> be seen <strong>as</strong> a ”smoothed out” version of a histogram,<br />

e.g. Figure 5.12: if one empirically me<strong>as</strong>ures values of a continuous r<strong>an</strong>dom<br />

variable repeatedly <strong>an</strong>d produces a histogram depicting relative frequencies of output<br />

r<strong>an</strong>ges, then this histogram will resemble the r<strong>an</strong>dom variable’s probability density<br />

(<strong>as</strong>suming that the variable is sampled sufficiently often <strong>an</strong>d the output r<strong>an</strong>ges<br />

are sufficiently narrow). Mathematically, the probability density function serves to<br />

represent the probability distribution of a r<strong>an</strong>dom variable.<br />

Definition C.8 Density Function<br />

A probability density function is <strong>an</strong>y function f(r) that describes the probability<br />

density in terms of the input variable r with the following characteristics:<br />

1. f(r) is greater th<strong>an</strong> or equal to zero for all values of r<br />

2. the total area under the graph is 1:<br />

∫ ∞<br />

−∞<br />

f(r)dr = 1<br />

The cumulated distribution function describes b<strong>as</strong>ed on the existence of a density<br />

the probability that the r<strong>an</strong>dom variable R takes on a value less th<strong>an</strong> or equal to r<br />

<strong>an</strong>d is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

Definition C.9 Cumulated Probability Function<br />

Define a r<strong>an</strong>dom variable R. The cumulated probability function is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

F (r) = Q(R ≤ r)<br />

{ ∫ r<br />

f(x)dx : if R is continuous<br />

−∞<br />

∑<br />

r Q(R = r t≤r t) = ∑ r q(r t≤r t) : if R is discrete 168 (C.7)<br />

185


C Mathematical Preliminaries<br />

The expected value of a r<strong>an</strong>dom variable or its me<strong>an</strong> is the sum of the probability of<br />

each possible outcome of the experiment multiplied by its payoff (”value”). Thus,<br />

it represents the average amount one ”expects” <strong>as</strong> the outcome of the r<strong>an</strong>dom trial<br />

when identical odds are repeated m<strong>an</strong>y times. More mathematical spoken, the me<strong>an</strong><br />

is like the center of gravity of a density, i.e. the location of the density. It is called<br />

the first moment of the density function <strong>an</strong>d defined <strong>as</strong> follows:<br />

Definition C.10 Me<strong>an</strong><br />

Define the r<strong>an</strong>dom variable R ∈ R (T ×1) describing all possible return realizations<br />

of a commodity index over time. The distribution of R is described by the density<br />

function f(r). Then the me<strong>an</strong> is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

µ = E(R) =<br />

{ ∫ ∞<br />

rf(r)dr : if R is continuous<br />

−∞<br />

∑ T<br />

t=1 r tq(r t ) : if R is discrete<br />

(C.8)<br />

The vari<strong>an</strong>ce me<strong>as</strong>ures the dispersion of the density function about the me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d is<br />

called the second moment. It indicates how possible values are spread around the<br />

expected value, i.e. me<strong>an</strong>. While the me<strong>an</strong> shows the location of the distribution,<br />

the vari<strong>an</strong>ce indicates the scale of the values.<br />

Definition C.11 Vari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

Define the r<strong>an</strong>dom variable R ∈ R (T ×1) describing all possible return realizations<br />

of a commodity index over time. The distribution of R is described by the density<br />

function f(r). The vari<strong>an</strong>ce is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

σ 2 = var(R) = E[(R − E[R]) 2 ] = E[R 2 ] − E[R] 2<br />

(C.9)<br />

A more underst<strong>an</strong>dable me<strong>as</strong>ure is the square root of the vari<strong>an</strong>ce, called the st<strong>an</strong>dard<br />

deviation: σ = √ σ 2 . As its name implies it gives in a st<strong>an</strong>dard form <strong>an</strong><br />

indication of the possible deviations from the me<strong>an</strong>.<br />

In fin<strong>an</strong>cial theory the most used distribution is the normal distribution. Actually<br />

it is a family of distributions, differing among their location <strong>an</strong>d scale parameters,<br />

i.e. their me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d vari<strong>an</strong>ce. The st<strong>an</strong>dard normal distribution is the normal<br />

distribution with me<strong>an</strong> zero <strong>an</strong>d vari<strong>an</strong>ce one.<br />

Definition C.12 Normal Distribution<br />

A r<strong>an</strong>dom variable R is called normally distributed with me<strong>an</strong> µ vari<strong>an</strong>ce σ 2 , i.e.<br />

R ∼ N(µ, σ 2 ),<br />

186


C.1 Statistical B<strong>as</strong>ics<br />

if its density function is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

f(x) =<br />

1<br />

x √ (x−µ)2<br />

e− 2σ 2<br />

2πσ2 A r<strong>an</strong>dom variable is called st<strong>an</strong>dard normally distributed if it is normally distributed<br />

with me<strong>an</strong> zero <strong>an</strong>d vari<strong>an</strong>ce one.<br />

Definition C.13 Log-normal distributed<br />

A r<strong>an</strong>dom variable R is called log normally, if ln R is normally distributed with<br />

me<strong>an</strong> µ vari<strong>an</strong>ce σ 2 , i.e.<br />

ln R ∼ N(µ, σ 2 ),<br />

if its density function is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

f(x) =<br />

1<br />

x √ (ln r−µ)2<br />

e− 2σ 2 , r > 0.<br />

2πσ2 The covari<strong>an</strong>ce describes a linear dependence between the vari<strong>an</strong>ce of two r<strong>an</strong>dom<br />

variables.<br />

Definition C.14 Covari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

Define the r<strong>an</strong>dom variables L <strong>an</strong>d R ∈ R (n×1) describing all possible return realizations<br />

of a two commodity indices over time. The covari<strong>an</strong>ce is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

cov(R, L) = E[(R − µ R )(L − µ L )]<br />

(C.10)<br />

The correlation is the normalized covari<strong>an</strong>ce.<br />

Definition C.15 Correlation<br />

Define the r<strong>an</strong>dom variables L <strong>an</strong>d R ∈ R (T ×1) describing all possible return realizations<br />

of a two commodity indices over time. The correlation is a st<strong>an</strong>dardized<br />

form of the covari<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

ρ =<br />

cov(R, L)<br />

√<br />

var(R)<br />

√<br />

var(L)<br />

= E[(R − µ R)(L − µ L )]<br />

√<br />

var(R)<br />

√<br />

var(L)<br />

(C.11)<br />

The autocorrelation describes a linear dependence between return realization at<br />

different points in time.<br />

187


C Mathematical Preliminaries<br />

Definition C.16 Autocorrelation<br />

Consider a weakly stationary return series r t . The correlation coefficient between<br />

r t <strong>an</strong>d r t−l is called the lag-l autocorrelation of r t <strong>an</strong>d defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

ρ l =<br />

cov(r t , r t−l )<br />

√<br />

var(rt ) √ var(r t−l ) = cov(r t, r t−l )<br />

var(r t )<br />

(C.12)<br />

While the me<strong>an</strong> is the average outcome of <strong>an</strong> experiment the medi<strong>an</strong> is the middle<br />

value of the sample.<br />

Definition C.17 Medi<strong>an</strong><br />

To be precise: Let r 1 , . . . , r T denote a r<strong>an</strong>dom sample. The order statistic is defined<br />

<strong>as</strong> r (1) ≤ r (2) ≤ . . . ≤ r (T ) . Then the medi<strong>an</strong> is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

¯r M =<br />

{<br />

r (<br />

T +1<br />

2 ) : if T is odd<br />

r ( T<br />

2<br />

) +r (1+ T 2 )<br />

2<br />

: if T is even.<br />

(C.13)<br />

Definition C.18 Qu<strong>an</strong>tile<br />

To be precise: Let r 1 , . . . , r T denote a r<strong>an</strong>dom sample <strong>an</strong>d R is the r<strong>an</strong>dom variable<br />

embodying all possible realizations r t . Let qu<strong>an</strong>tile q α is defined <strong>as</strong> the value that α%<br />

of the possible realizations are smaller th<strong>an</strong> q α , i.e.<br />

Q(R ≤ q α ) = α<br />

(C.14)<br />

Definition C.19 Skewness<br />

Define the r<strong>an</strong>dom variable R ∈ R (T ×1) describing all possible return realizations of<br />

a commodity index over time <strong>an</strong>d let µ <strong>an</strong>d σ be their me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation.<br />

The coefficients of skewness S is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

Definition C.20 Kurtosis<br />

S = E( R − µ ) 3 (C.15)<br />

σ<br />

Define the r<strong>an</strong>dom variable R ∈ R (T ×1) describing all possible return realizations of<br />

a commodity index over time <strong>an</strong>d let µ <strong>an</strong>d σ be their me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d st<strong>an</strong>dard deviation.<br />

The coefficients of kurtosis K is defined <strong>as</strong>:<br />

Definition C.21 Order Statistic<br />

K = E( R − µ ) 4 − 3 (C.16)<br />

σ<br />

Let {r 1 , . . . , r T } be a sample of T independent observations of the r<strong>an</strong>dom variable<br />

188


C.1 Statistical B<strong>as</strong>ics<br />

R. Arr<strong>an</strong>ge the r t in <strong>as</strong>cending order of magnitude <strong>an</strong>d denote the ordered set by<br />

(r (1) , . . . , r (T ) ), so that: (r (1) ≤ . . . ≤ r (T ) ). (r (1) , . . . , r (T ) ) is called the order statistic.<br />

Definition C.22 Distribution of Order Statistic<br />

Let f(r) be the probability density function <strong>an</strong>d F(r) be the cumulative distribution<br />

function of R.<br />

follows:<br />

Proof:<br />

Then the probability density of the k’th statistic c<strong>an</strong> be found <strong>as</strong><br />

f R(k) (r) =<br />

T !<br />

(k − 1)!(T − k)! F (r)k−1 (1 − F (r)) T −k f(r) (C.17)<br />

f R(k) (r) = d<br />

dx F R (k)<br />

(r) = d<br />

dx Q(R (k) ≤ r)<br />

= d Q(at leats k of the T R’s are ≤ r)<br />

dx<br />

= d Q(≥ ksuccesses in T trials)<br />

dx<br />

T∑<br />

= d<br />

dx<br />

= d<br />

dx<br />

=<br />

T∑<br />

i=k<br />

i=k<br />

T∑<br />

i=k<br />

( T<br />

j<br />

)<br />

Q(R 1 ≤ r) j (1 − Q(R 1 ≤ r)) T −j<br />

( T<br />

j<br />

)<br />

F (r) j (1 − F (r)) T −j<br />

( T<br />

j<br />

)<br />

(jF (r) j−1 f(r)(1 − F (r)) T −j<br />

+ F (r) j (T − j)(1 − F (r)) T −j−1 (−f(r)))<br />

T∑<br />

( ) T − 1<br />

= (T F (r) j−1 (1 − F (r)) T −j<br />

j − 1<br />

i=k<br />

( ) T − 1<br />

− T F (r) j (1 − F (r)) T −j−1 )f(r)<br />

j<br />

T∑<br />

−1 ( ) T − 1<br />

= T f(r)(<br />

F (r) j (1 − F (r))<br />

j<br />

i=k−1<br />

(T −1)−j<br />

T∑<br />

( ) T − 1<br />

−<br />

F (r) j (1 − F (r)) (T −1)−j )<br />

j<br />

i=k<br />

( ) T − 1<br />

= T f(r)( F (r) k−1 (1 − F (r))<br />

k − 1<br />

( ) T − 1<br />

− F (r) T (T −1)−T<br />

(1 − F (r)) )<br />

T<br />

} {{ }<br />

0<br />

T !<br />

=<br />

(k − 1)!(T − k)! F (r)k−1 (1 − F (r)) T −k f(r)<br />

(T −1)−(k−1)<br />

✷<br />

189


C Mathematical Preliminaries<br />

C.2 Probability Theory<br />

The following definitions are inspired by [Zagst 2002]. For a detailed introduction<br />

to fin<strong>an</strong>cial market theory, ple<strong>as</strong>e refer to it.<br />

Definition C.23 Me<strong>as</strong>urable<br />

A k-dimensional function f : Ω ↦→ R k is called (F − B(R k )-) me<strong>as</strong>urable or simply<br />

(F-) me<strong>as</strong>urable if<br />

f −1 (B) = {ω ∈ Ω : f(ω) ∈ B} ∈ F<br />

∀B ∈ B<br />

From this point on we <strong>as</strong>sume that we are working on a complete probability space<br />

(Ω, F, Q). In this c<strong>as</strong>e a k dimensional me<strong>as</strong>urable function X : Ω ↦→ R k , k ∈ N,<br />

is called a r<strong>an</strong>dom vector. For k = 1 we call R a r<strong>an</strong>dom variable. The smallest<br />

sigma-Algebra containing all sets X −1 (B) = {ω ∈ Ω : X(ω) ∈ B}, where B runs<br />

through the Borel sigma-Algebra B(R k ), is called the sigma-Algebra generated by<br />

X, <strong>an</strong>d will be denoted by F(R).<br />

Definition C.24 Conditional Expectation<br />

Let X be <strong>an</strong> integrable r<strong>an</strong>dom variable on the probability space (Ω, F, Q) <strong>an</strong>d G ⊂ F<br />

be a sub-sigma-Algebra of F. The conditional expectation of X given G is implicitly<br />

defined to be the G-me<strong>as</strong>urable function E Q [X|G] with<br />

∫ ∫<br />

XdQ = E Q [X|G]dQ ∀A ∈ G Q − a.s.<br />

A<br />

A<br />

The function<br />

Q : F ↦→ [0, 1]<br />

is a probability m<strong>as</strong>s.<br />

For the main properties of the conditional expectation see [Zagst 2002].<br />

Definition C.25 Filtration<br />

A filtration F is a non-decre<strong>as</strong>ing family of sub-sigma-algebr<strong>as</strong> (F t ) t≥0 with F t ⊂ F<br />

<strong>an</strong>d F s ⊂ F t for all 0 ≤ s < t < ∞. We call (Ω, F, Q, F) a filtered probability space,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d require that<br />

1. F 0 contains all subsets of the (Q-) null sets of F,<br />

2. F is right-continuous, i.e. F t = F t+ := ∩ s>t F s<br />

190


C.2 Probability Theory<br />

F t represents the information available at time t, <strong>an</strong>d F = (F t ) t≥0 describes the flow<br />

of information over time, where we suppose that we don’t lose information <strong>as</strong> time<br />

p<strong>as</strong>ses by.<br />

The price behavior of fin<strong>an</strong>cial products over time is usually described by a so-called<br />

stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process.<br />

Definition C.26 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Process<br />

A stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process (vector process) is a family X = (X(t)) t≥0 of r<strong>an</strong>dom variables<br />

(vectors) defined on the filtered probability space (Ω, F, Q, F). We say that:<br />

1. X is adapted (to the filtration F) if X t = X(t) is (F t -) me<strong>as</strong>urable for all<br />

t ≥ 0<br />

2. X is me<strong>as</strong>urable of the mapping X : [0, ∞]×Ω → R k , k ∈ N is B([0, ∞))⊗F-<br />

B(R k )−me<strong>as</strong>urable<br />

3. X is progressively me<strong>as</strong>urable if the mapping X : [0, t] × Ω → R k , k ∈ N<br />

is B([0, t]) ⊗ F t -B(R k )−me<strong>as</strong>urable for each t ≥ 0.<br />

Note that we either write X t or X(t), whichever is more comfortable. Also note<br />

that a stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process is a function in t for each fixed or realized ωinΩ. If the<br />

stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process X is me<strong>as</strong>urable, the mapping X(·, ω) : [0, ∞) ↦→ R k , k ∈ N,<br />

B([0, ∞)) ⊗ B(R k ) is me<strong>as</strong>urable for each fixed ωinΩ. For each fixed ωinΩ we call<br />

X(ω) = (X t (ω)) t≥0 = (X(t, ω)) t≥0 a path or realization of the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process.<br />

Definition C.27 L 2 [0, T]-Prozess<br />

Let (Ω, F, Q, F) bw a filtered probability space <strong>an</strong>d X be a stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process adapted<br />

to F. We call a stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process L 2 [0, T]-process, if X is progressively me<strong>as</strong>urable<br />

<strong>an</strong>d<br />

∫ T<br />

‖X‖ 2 T := E Q[ X 2 (t)dt] < ∞.<br />

0<br />

One of the atoms of modern fin<strong>an</strong>ce is the following special stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process called<br />

Wiener process, sometimes also known <strong>as</strong> Browni<strong>an</strong> motion. 169<br />

Definition C.28 Wiener process Let (Ω, F, Q, F) be a filtered probability space.<br />

The stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process W = (W t ) t≥0 = (W (t)) t≥0 is called a Q- Browni<strong>an</strong> motion or<br />

Q- Wiener process if<br />

1. W (0) = 0 Q-a.s.<br />

169 For further details to the naming conventions see [Zagst 2002].<br />

191


C Mathematical Preliminaries<br />

2. W h<strong>as</strong> independent increments, i.e. W (t) − W (s) is independent of W (t ′ ) −<br />

W (s ′ ) for all 0 ≤ s ′ ≤ t ′ ≤ s ≤ t < ∞<br />

3. W h<strong>as</strong> stationary increments, i.e. the distribution of W (t + u) − W (t) only<br />

depends on u for u ≥ 0<br />

4. Under Q, W h<strong>as</strong> Gaussi<strong>an</strong> increments, i.e. for 0 ≤ s ≤ t:<br />

W (t) − W (s) ∼ N(0, t − s).<br />

with the definitions of C.12.<br />

5. W h<strong>as</strong> continuous path Q-a.s.<br />

We call W with W T = (W 1 , . . . , W m ) = (W 1 (t), . . . , W m (t)) t≥0 a m-dimensional<br />

Wiener process, m ∈ N, if its components W j , j = 1, . . . , m, m ∈ N, are independent<br />

Wiener processes.<br />

Definition C.29 Martingale Let (Ω, F, Q, F) be a filtered probability space. A<br />

stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process X = {X(t); t ≥ 0}, that is adapted with E Q [|X(t)|] < ∞, ∀t ≥ 0,<br />

is called:<br />

martingale relative to (Q, F), if E Q [X(t)|F s ] = X(s) Q-a.s. ∀0 ≤ s ≤ t < ∞<br />

super-martingale relative to (Q, F), if E Q [X(t)|F s ] ≤ X(s) Q-a.s. ∀0 ≤ s ≤<br />

t < ∞<br />

sub-martingale relative to (Q, F), if E Q [X(t)|F s ] ≥ X(s) Q-a.s. ∀0 ≤ s ≤<br />

t < ∞<br />

192


C.3 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Differential Equations<br />

C.3 Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Differential Equations<br />

A major tool to describe the price behavior of fin<strong>an</strong>cial <strong>as</strong>sets <strong>an</strong>d derivatives is the<br />

Itô process.<br />

Definition C.30 Itô process<br />

Let W = (W 1 , . . . , W m ), m ∈ N, be a m-dimensional Wiener process. A stoch<strong>as</strong>tic<br />

process X = (X(t)) t≥0 is called <strong>an</strong> Itô process if ∀t ≥ 0 we have:<br />

X(t) = X 0 +<br />

= X 0 +<br />

∫ t<br />

0<br />

∫ t<br />

µ(s)ds +<br />

µ(s)ds +<br />

∫ t<br />

0<br />

j=1 0<br />

0<br />

m∑<br />

σ(s)dW (s)<br />

∫ t<br />

σ j (s)dW j (s),<br />

(C.18)<br />

where X 0 is (F 0 -)me<strong>as</strong>urable <strong>an</strong>d µ = (µ(t)) t≥0 <strong>an</strong>d σ(t) = (σ 1 (t), . . . , σ m (t)) t≥0 are<br />

(m-dimensional) progressively me<strong>as</strong>urable stoch<strong>as</strong>tic processes with<br />

<strong>an</strong>d<br />

∀t ≥ 0, j = 1, . . . , m.<br />

∫ t<br />

0<br />

∫ t<br />

|µ(s)| ds < ∞ Q − a.s. , (C.19)<br />

0<br />

σ 2 j (s)ds < ∞ Q − a.s. (C.20)<br />

A n-dimensional Itô process is given by a vector X = (X 1 , . . . , X n ), n ∈ N, with<br />

each X i being <strong>an</strong> Itô process, i = 1, . . . , n.<br />

For convenience we write symbolically instead of (C.18)<br />

m∑<br />

dX(t) = µ(t)dt + σ(t)dW (t) = µ(t)dt + σ j (t)dW j (t);<br />

<strong>an</strong>d call this a stoch<strong>as</strong>tic differential equation (SDE).<br />

Definition C.31 Quadratic Covari<strong>an</strong>ce Process<br />

Let m ∈ N <strong>an</strong>d W = (W 1 , . . . , W m ) be a m-dimensional Wiener process. Furthermore,<br />

let (X 1 (t)) t≥0 <strong>an</strong>d (X 2 (t)) t≥0 be two Itô processes with<br />

m∑<br />

dX i (t) = µ i (t)dt + σ i (t)dW (t) = µ i (t)dt + σ ij dW j (t), i = 1, 2. (C.21)<br />

j=1<br />

j=1<br />

193


C Mathematical Preliminaries<br />

Then we call the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process < X 1 , X 2 >= (< X 1 (t), X 2 (t) >) t≥0 defined by<br />

< X 1 , X 2 >:=<br />

m∑<br />

∫ t<br />

j=1 0<br />

σ 1j (s)σ 2j (s)ds<br />

(C.22)<br />

the quadratic covari<strong>an</strong>ce (process) of X 1 <strong>an</strong>d X 2 . If X 1 = X 2 =: X we call the<br />

stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process < X >:=< X, X > the quadratic variation (process) of X. 170<br />

Theorem C.1 (Itô´s Lemma) Let W = (W 1 , . . . , W m ) be a m-dimensional Wiener<br />

process, m ∈ N,<strong>an</strong>d X = (X(t)) t≥0 be <strong>an</strong> Itô process with<br />

m∑<br />

dX(t) = µ(t)dt + σ(t)dW (t) = µ(t)dt + σ j (t)dW j (t)<br />

Furthermore, let G : R × [0, ∞) ↦→ R be twice continuously differentiable in the first<br />

variable, with derivatives denoted by G X <strong>an</strong>d G XX , <strong>an</strong>d once continuously differentiable<br />

in the second, with derivative denoted by G t . Then we have ∀t ∈ [0, ∞)<br />

j=1<br />

dG(X(t), t) = G t (X(t), t)dt + G X (X(t), t)dX(t) + 1 2 G XX(X(t), t)d < X(t), X(t) ><br />

=<br />

(<br />

G t (X(t), t) + G X (X(t), t)µ(t) + 1 2 G XX(X(t), t)<br />

+ G X (X(t), t)<br />

m∑<br />

σ j (t)dW j (t)<br />

j=1<br />

m∑<br />

j=1<br />

)<br />

σj 2 (t) dt<br />

Whereby, the W j , j = 1, . . . , m, are <strong>as</strong>sumed to be independent.<br />

170 For a detailed definition see [Zagst 2002].<br />

194


C.4 Equivalent Me<strong>as</strong>ure<br />

C.4 Equivalent Me<strong>as</strong>ure<br />

Definition C.32 Equivalent Me<strong>as</strong>ure<br />

Let Q <strong>an</strong>d ˜Q be two me<strong>as</strong>ures defined on the same me<strong>as</strong>urable space (Ω, F). We say<br />

˜Q is absolutely continuous with respect to Q, written ˜Q ≪ Q,if ˜Q(A) = 0 whenever<br />

Q(A) = 0, A ∈ F. If both ˜Q ≪ Q <strong>an</strong>d Q ≪ ˜Q, we call Q <strong>an</strong>d ˜Q equivalent me<strong>as</strong>ures<br />

<strong>an</strong>d denote this by ˜Q ∼ Q.<br />

The definition of equivalent me<strong>as</strong>ures states that two me<strong>as</strong>ures are equivalent if <strong>an</strong>d<br />

only if they have same null sets.<br />

Definition C.33 Radon Nikodym Derivative<br />

Let Q be a sigma-finite me<strong>as</strong>ure <strong>an</strong>d ˜Q be a me<strong>as</strong>ure on the me<strong>as</strong>urable space (Ω, F)<br />

with ˜Q < ∞. Then ˜Q ≪ Q if <strong>an</strong>d only if there exists <strong>an</strong> integrable function f ≥ 0<br />

Q-a.s. such that<br />

∫<br />

˜Q(A) =<br />

A<br />

fdQ<br />

∀A ∈ F<br />

f is called the Radon-Nikodym derivative of ˜Q with respect to Q <strong>an</strong>d is also written<br />

<strong>as</strong> f = d ˜Q<br />

dQ .<br />

Let γ = (γ(t)) t≥0 be a m-dimensional progressively me<strong>as</strong>urable stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process,<br />

m ∈ N, with<br />

∫ t<br />

0<br />

γ 2 j (s)ds < ∞ Q − a.s. ∀t ≥ 0, j = 1, . . . , m<br />

Let the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process L(γ) = (L(γ, t)) t≥0 = (L(γ(t), t)) t≥0 , ∀t ≥ 0 be defined<br />

by<br />

L(γ, t) = e − R t<br />

R<br />

0 γ(s)′ dW (s)− 1 t<br />

2 0 ||gamma(s)||ds<br />

Note that the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process X(γ) = (X(γ, t)) t≥0 = (X(γ(t), t)) t≥0 with<br />

or<br />

X(γ, t) :=<br />

∫ t<br />

0<br />

γ(s) ′ dW (s) + 1 2<br />

∫ t<br />

0<br />

||γ(s)|| 2 ds<br />

dX(γ, t) := 1 2 ||γ(t)||2 dt + γ(t) ′ dW (t)<br />

is ∀t ∈ [0, ∞) <strong>an</strong> Itô process with with µ(γ(t), t) = 1 2 ||γ(t)||2 = 1 2<br />

∑ m<br />

j=1 γ2 j (t) <strong>an</strong>d<br />

σ(γ(t), t) = γ(t) ′ . Thus, using the tr<strong>an</strong>sformation G : R×[0, ∞) ↦→ R with G(x, t) =<br />

e −x <strong>an</strong>d Itô’ lemma <strong>as</strong> of C.1 with G(X(γ, t), t) = e −X(γ,t) = L(γ, t) we get: 171<br />

171 For a detailed calculation see [Zagst 2002].<br />

dL(γ, t) = −L(γ, t)γ(t) ′ dW (t)<br />

195


C Mathematical Preliminaries<br />

Theorem C.2 Novikov Condition<br />

Let γ <strong>an</strong>d L(γ) be <strong>as</strong> defined above. Then L(γ) = (L(γ, t)) t∈[0,T ] os a continuous<br />

(Q -) martingale if<br />

E Q<br />

[e 1 2<br />

R t<br />

0 ||γ(s)||2 ds]<br />

< ∞<br />

For each T ≥ 0 we define the me<strong>as</strong>ure ˜Q = Q L(γ,T ) on the me<strong>as</strong>ure space (Ω, F T ) by<br />

∫<br />

˜Q(A) := E Q [1 A ∗ L(γ, T )] = L(γ, T )dQ<br />

A<br />

∀A ∈ F T<br />

which is the probability me<strong>as</strong>ure if L(γ, T ) is a (Q -) martingale. In this c<strong>as</strong>e,<br />

L(γ, T ) is a (Q -) density of ˜Q, i.e. L(γ, T ) = d ˜Q on (Ω, F dQ T ). The following Girs<strong>an</strong>ov<br />

theorem shows how the adequate (tildeQ -) Wiener process ˜W<br />

( )<br />

= ˜W (t) is<br />

constructed, starting with a (Q -) Wiener process W = (W (t)) t∈[0,T ]<br />

.<br />

Theorem C.3 Girs<strong>an</strong>ov Theorem<br />

t∈[0,T ]<br />

Let W = (W 1 , . . . , W m ) = (W (t) 1 , . . . , W (t) m ) t∈[0,T ]<br />

be a m-dimensional (Q -)<br />

Wiener Process, m ∈ N, γ, L(γ), ˜Q <strong>an</strong>d T ∈ [0, ∞) be defined <strong>as</strong> above, <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

m-dimensional stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process ˜W = ( ˜W 1 , . . . , ˜W<br />

(<br />

m ) = ˜W (t)1 , . . . , ˜W<br />

)<br />

(t) m<br />

be defined by<br />

d˜W (t) := γ(t)dt + dW (t), t ∈ [0, T ]<br />

t∈[0,T ]<br />

If the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process L(γ) is a (Q -) martingale, then the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process ˜W<br />

is a m-dimensional ( ˜Q -) Wiener Process on the me<strong>as</strong>ure space (Ω, F T ).<br />

196


C.5 Feynm<strong>an</strong>-Kac Representation<br />

C.5 Feynm<strong>an</strong>-Kac Representation<br />

We now will move on to solve stoch<strong>as</strong>tic differential equations. For it, we consider<br />

a special form of stoch<strong>as</strong>tic differential equation. To do this, let µ : R × [0, ∞) → R<br />

<strong>an</strong>d σ : R×[0, ∞) → R m be me<strong>as</strong>urable functions (with respect to the corresponding<br />

Borel sigma-Algebr<strong>as</strong>) with<br />

∫ t<br />

0<br />

|µ i (s)|ds < ∞ <strong>an</strong>d<br />

∫ t<br />

0<br />

σ 2 ij(s)ds < ∞ Q − a.s., (C.23)<br />

<strong>an</strong>d j = 1, . . . , m, i = 1, . . . , n, n <strong>an</strong>d m ∈ N <strong>an</strong>d ∀t ≥ 0.<br />

Definition C.34 Strong Solution of the SDE<br />

If there exists a n-dimensional stoch<strong>as</strong>tic process X = (X(t)) t≥0 on the probability<br />

space (Ω, F, Q, F) satisfying (C.23), i.e. <strong>an</strong> Itô process, such that ∀t ≥ 0<br />

X(t) = x +<br />

∫ t<br />

µ(X(s), s)ds +<br />

∫ t<br />

0<br />

0<br />

σ(X(s), s)dW (s)<br />

Q − a.s.,<br />

X(0) = x, x ∈ R n ,<br />

fixed,<br />

we call X the strong solution of the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic differential equation (SDE)<br />

dX(t) = µ(X(t), t)dt + σ(X(t), t)dW (t) ∀t ≥ 0 <strong>an</strong>d X(0) = x. (C.24)<br />

Theorem C.4 Existence <strong>an</strong>d Uniqueness<br />

Let µ <strong>an</strong>d σ of the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic differential equation (SDE) be continuous functions<br />

such that for ∀t ≥ 0, x, y ∈ R n <strong>an</strong>d for K > 0 the following conditions hold:<br />

‖µ(x, t) − µ(y, t)‖ + ‖σ(x, t) − σ(y, t)‖ ≤ K ‖x − y‖ ,<br />

(Lipschitz − Condition)<br />

‖µ(x, t)‖ 2 + ‖σ(x, t)‖ 2 ≤ K 2 (1 + ‖x‖ 2 ),<br />

(Growth − Condition)<br />

Then there exists a unique, continuous strong solution X = (X(t)) t≥0 von (C.24) of<br />

(SDE) <strong>an</strong>d a const<strong>an</strong>t C, depending on K <strong>an</strong>d T > 0, such that<br />

E Q [‖X(t)‖ 2 ] ≤ C(1 + ‖x‖ 2 )e Ct ∀t ∈ [0, T ].<br />

To move on to the so-called Feynm<strong>an</strong>-Kac Representation the following definition<br />

is very helpful.<br />

197


C Mathematical Preliminaries<br />

Definition C.35 characteristic Operator<br />

Let X = (X(t)) t≥0 be the unique solution of the stoch<strong>as</strong>tic differential equation<br />

( (C.24)) under the <strong>as</strong>sumptions of Theorem C.4. Then the operator D defined by<br />

(Dυ)(x, t) = υ t (x, t) + µ(x, t)υ x (x, t) + 1 2 σ2 (x, t)υ xx (x, t)<br />

with υ : R × [0, ∞) → R twice continuously differentiable in x, once continuously<br />

differentiable in t <strong>an</strong>d<br />

m∑<br />

σ 2 (x, t) = σj 2 (x, t)<br />

j=1<br />

is called the characteristic operator for X(t).<br />

The operator is used to define the so-called Cauchy problem.<br />

Definition C.36 Cauchy Problem<br />

Let D : R → R <strong>an</strong>d r : R×[0, T ] → R be continuous <strong>an</strong>d T > 0 be arbitrary but fixed.<br />

Then, the Cauchy problem is stated <strong>as</strong> follows: Find a function υ : R × [0, T ] → R,<br />

which is continuously differentiable in t <strong>an</strong>d twice continuously differentiable in x<br />

<strong>an</strong>d solves the partial differential equation (sometimes called Kolmogorov equation)<br />

Dυ(x, t) = r(x, t)υ(x, t) ∀(x, t) ∈ R × [0, T ], (C.25)<br />

υ(x, T ) = D(x) ∀x ∈ R. (C.26)<br />

Theorem C.5 Feynm<strong>an</strong>-Kac Representation<br />

Under the <strong>as</strong>sumption, that the function µ, σ, r, v und D <strong>as</strong> defined above, satisfy<br />

sufficient regulatory conditions, the solution v of the Cauchy problem os given by the<br />

following conditional expectation called Feynm<strong>an</strong>-Kac representation:<br />

v(x, t) = E x,t<br />

Q<br />

[e − R ]<br />

T<br />

t r(X(s),s)ds D(X(T ))<br />

(C.27)<br />

with X(0) = x.<br />

198


D Program Codes<br />

The following section show the program codes which were used to generate the<br />

results of Section 6. I produced the programs in collaboration with my colleague<br />

at <strong>risklab</strong> germ<strong>an</strong>y Dr. Wolfg<strong>an</strong>g Mader. I appreciate his expertise <strong>an</strong>d th<strong>an</strong>k him<br />

very much for his support.<br />

D.1 Portfolio Allocation with <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

% Function calculates the Efficient Frontier with Commodites b<strong>as</strong>ed on bootstrapped<br />

%data<br />

% Author’s Information<br />

%———————————————————————<br />

% <strong>risklab</strong> germ<strong>an</strong>y GmbH<br />

% Nypmhenburger Str<strong>as</strong>se 112 - 116<br />

% D-80636 Muenchen<br />

% Germ<strong>an</strong>y<br />

% Internet: www.<strong>risklab</strong>.de<br />

% email: info@<strong>risklab</strong>.de<br />

% Implementation Date: 2006 - 09 - 27<br />

% Author: Dr. Wolfg<strong>an</strong>g Mader, Maria Heiden<br />

%———————————————————————<br />

% Calculate Efficient Frontier<br />

returns = RollingAverage;<br />

Steps = 500;<br />

ub = [1;1;1]; i = 1;<br />

% Portfolio with <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

for mu = min(me<strong>an</strong>(returns)):(max(me<strong>an</strong>(returns))-min(me<strong>an</strong>(returns))) ...<br />

/Steps:max(me<strong>an</strong>(returns))<br />

199


D Program Codes<br />

[weights,value] = szenoptiRM(returns, mu, ub);<br />

weightsPF(i,:)=weights’;<br />

muePF(i)=mu;<br />

riskPF(i)=value;<br />

i=i+1;<br />

end<br />

muePF=muePF’; riskPF=riskPF’;<br />

ub = [1;1];<br />

i = 1;<br />

returnsOld = returns(:,2:3);<br />

% Portfolio without <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

for mu = min(me<strong>an</strong>(returnsOld)):(max(me<strong>an</strong>(returnsOld))-min(me<strong>an</strong>(returnsOld)))<br />

... /Steps:max(me<strong>an</strong>(returnsOld))<br />

[weights,value] = szenoptiRM(returnsOld, mu, ub);<br />

weightsPFNo(i,:)=weights’;<br />

muePFNo(i)=mu;<br />

riskPFNo(i)=value;<br />

i=i+1;<br />

end<br />

muePFNo = muePFNo’; riskPFNo =riskPFNo’;<br />

% plotting efficient frontiers<br />

figure(1) plot(riskPF,muePF,’-.r’) hold on<br />

plot(riskPFNo,muePFNo,’-.k’)<br />

legend hurdle noCom grid on<br />

200


D.2 Hurdle Rate<br />

D.2 Hurdle Rate<br />

% Hurdle Rate is the return <strong>an</strong> alternative h<strong>as</strong> to produce to be allocated in a<br />

% Stock-Bond-Portfolio<br />

% Author’s Information<br />

%———————————————————————<br />

% <strong>risklab</strong> germ<strong>an</strong>y GmbH<br />

% Nypmhenburger Str<strong>as</strong>se 112 - 116<br />

% D-80636 Muenchen<br />

% Germ<strong>an</strong>y<br />

% Internet: www.<strong>risklab</strong>.de<br />

% email: info@<strong>risklab</strong>.de<br />

% Implementation Date: 2006 - 09 - 27<br />

% Author: Dr. Wolfg<strong>an</strong>g Mader, Maria Heiden<br />

%———————————————————————<br />

% Start Values<br />

returns = RollingAverage;<br />

allocationBonds = .75;<br />

startHurdle = .0385;<br />

stepsImplied = .0001;<br />

outperform<strong>an</strong>ceTrigger = .0001;<br />

me<strong>an</strong>Bonds = me<strong>an</strong>(returns(:,3));<br />

me<strong>an</strong>Stocks = me<strong>an</strong>(returns(:,2));<br />

me<strong>an</strong>Alternative = me<strong>an</strong>(returns(:,1));<br />

sdBonds = std(returns(:,3));<br />

sdStocks = std(returns(:,2));<br />

sdAlternative = std(returns(:,1));<br />

201


D Program Codes<br />

warning off;<br />

% Reference Values of Start Allocation (25% Stocks, 75% Bonds)<br />

% Reference Portfolio St<strong>an</strong>dard Deviation<br />

stdPFTest=std(returns(:,2:3)*[(1-allocationBonds);allocationBonds]);<br />

% Reference Portfolio Me<strong>an</strong><br />

muPFTest = (1-allocationBonds)*me<strong>an</strong>Stocks+allocationBonds*me<strong>an</strong>Bonds;<br />

% Check Optimization<br />

ub = [1;1];<br />

[weights,mue] = szenoptiValue(returns(:,2:3), stdPFTest, ub);<br />

stdev = std(returns(:,2:3)*weights);<br />

% Loop for Hurdle Rate<br />

impliedHurdleRate = startHurdle;<br />

ub=[1;1;1];<br />

% Move Returndistribution of <strong>Commodities</strong> to Start Value<br />

returns(:,1) = returns(:,1)-me<strong>an</strong>(returns(:,1))+impliedHurdleRate;<br />

while (impliedHurdleRate ¡ me<strong>an</strong>Alternative)<br />

disp(’————————————————————’)<br />

returns(:,1) = returns(:,1) + stepsImplied;<br />

disp(’impliedHurdleRate’)<br />

me<strong>an</strong>(returns(:,1))<br />

[weights,value] = szenoptiValue(returns, stdPFTest, ub);<br />

202


D.2 Hurdle Rate<br />

disp(’current weights’)<br />

weights<br />

disp(’current return’)<br />

value<br />

disp(’target return’)<br />

muPFTest<br />

disp(’STDEV’)<br />

std(returns*weights)<br />

% Hurdle Rate is found if new portfolio return is bigger th<strong>an</strong> reference portfolio<br />

% return plus outperform<strong>an</strong>ce-trigger<br />

returnTest = value;<br />

if <strong>an</strong>d(returnTest¿muPFTest+outperform<strong>an</strong>ceTrigger,weights(1)¿0)<br />

break<br />

end<br />

impliedHurdleRate = impliedHurdleRate + stepsImplied;<br />

end<br />

% Calculating Efficient Frontiers<br />

Steps = 500;<br />

i = 1;<br />

for mu = min(me<strong>an</strong>(returns)):(max(me<strong>an</strong>(returns))-min(me<strong>an</strong>(returns))) ...<br />

/Steps:max(me<strong>an</strong>(returns))<br />

[weights,value] = szenoptiRM(returns, mu, ub);<br />

weightsPFHurd(i,:)=weights’;<br />

muPFHurd(i)=mu;<br />

riskPFHurd(i)=value;<br />

i=i+1;<br />

end<br />

203


D Program Codes<br />

muPFHurd=muPFHurd’; riskPFHurd=riskPFHurd’;<br />

ub = [1;1];<br />

i = 1;<br />

returnsOld = returns(:,2:3);<br />

for mu = min(me<strong>an</strong>(returnsOld)):(max(me<strong>an</strong>(returnsOld))-min(me<strong>an</strong>(returnsOld)))<br />

... /Steps:max(me<strong>an</strong>(returnsOld))<br />

[weights,value] = szenoptiRM(returnsOld, mu, ub);<br />

weightsPFNo(i,:)=weights’;<br />

muPFNo(i)=mu;<br />

riskPFNo(i)=value;<br />

i=i+1;<br />

end<br />

muPFNo = muPFNo’;<br />

riskPFNo =riskPFNo’;<br />

% plotting efficient frontiers<br />

figure(1)<br />

plot(riskPFHurd,muPFHurd,’-.r’) hold on<br />

plot(riskPFNo,muPFNo,’-.k’)<br />

legend hurdle noCom<br />

204


D.3 Help Function<br />

D.3 Help Function<br />

% Function calculates the efficient frontier<br />

function [weights,value] = szenoptiValue(returns, riskTarget, boundAlternatives)<br />

% Author’s Information<br />

%———————————————————————<br />

% <strong>risklab</strong> germ<strong>an</strong>y GmbH<br />

% Nypmhenburger Str<strong>as</strong>se 112 - 116<br />

% D-80636 Muenchen<br />

% Germ<strong>an</strong>y<br />

% Internet: www.<strong>risklab</strong>.de<br />

% email: info@<strong>risklab</strong>.de<br />

% Implementation Date: 2006 - 09 - 27<br />

% Author: Dr. Wolfg<strong>an</strong>g Mader, Maria Heiden<br />

%———————————————————————<br />

T=size(returns,1);<br />

N=size(returns,2);<br />

x0=repmat(1/N,1,N)’;<br />

A=[];<br />

b = [];<br />

Aeq(1,:)=ones(1,N);<br />

beq =[1];<br />

lb=zeros(N,1);<br />

ub=[1;1;boundAlternatives];<br />

optimizationOptions = optimset(’Display’, ’off’, ’LargeScale’, ’off’);<br />

[weights,value]=fmincon(@(x) optiMe<strong>an</strong>(x,returns),x0,A,b,Aeq,beq,lb,ub, ...<br />

@(x) mycon(x,returns,riskTarget),optimizationOptions);<br />

205


D Program Codes<br />

value = -value;<br />

function [c,ceq] = mycon(w,returns,riskTarget) objective=optiStd(w,returns);<br />

c = [];<br />

% Compute nonlinear inequalities at x<br />

ceq = objective - riskTarget;<br />

function objective = optiMe<strong>an</strong>(w,returns)<br />

objective=-me<strong>an</strong>(returns*w);<br />

% Function calculates the efficient frontier<br />

function [weights,value] = szenoptiRM(returns, muTarget, ub)<br />

% Author’s Information<br />

%———————————————————————<br />

% <strong>risklab</strong> germ<strong>an</strong>y GmbH<br />

% Nypmhenburger Str<strong>as</strong>se 112 - 116<br />

% D-80636 Muenchen<br />

% Germ<strong>an</strong>y<br />

% Internet: www.<strong>risklab</strong>.de<br />

% email: info@<strong>risklab</strong>.de<br />

% Implementation Date: 2006 - 09 - 27<br />

% Author: Dr. Wolfg<strong>an</strong>g Mader, Maria Heiden<br />

%———————————————————————<br />

T=size(returns,1);<br />

N=size(returns,2);<br />

x0=repmat(1/N,1,N)’;<br />

A=[];<br />

b = [];<br />

Aeq(1,:)=ones(1,N);<br />

Aeq(2,:)=me<strong>an</strong>(returns);<br />

beq=[1;muTarget];<br />

lb=zeros(N,1);<br />

206


D.3 Help Function<br />

optimizationOptions = optimset(’Display’, ’off’, ’LargeScale’, ’off’);<br />

[weights,value]=fmincon(@(x) optiStd(x,returns),x0,A,b,Aeq,beq,lb,ub, ...<br />

[],optimizationOptions);<br />

function objective = optiStd(w,returns)<br />

objective=std(returns*w);<br />

207


References<br />

References<br />

[Aitken 1935] A.C. Aitken (1935): On Le<strong>as</strong>t Squares <strong>an</strong>d linear Combination of<br />

Observations, Proceedings of the Royal Society of Edinburgh, vol. 55, 42.<br />

[Alex<strong>an</strong>der 2001] Carol Alex<strong>an</strong>der (2001):<br />

Sons Publications<br />

Market Models, John Wiley <strong>an</strong>d<br />

[Anderson 2000] Mark J.P. Anderson (2000): The H<strong>an</strong>dbook of Alternative<br />

<strong>Asset</strong>s, John Wiley <strong>an</strong>d Sons Publications<br />

[Anderson D<strong>an</strong>thine 1983] R.W. Anderson <strong>an</strong>d J.P. D<strong>an</strong>thine (1983): The<br />

time pattern of hedging <strong>an</strong>d the volatility of futures markets, Review of<br />

Economic Studies, 50: 249-266<br />

[Bamberg Baur 2002] G. Bamberg und F. Baur (2002): Statistik, Oldenborg<br />

Verlag, München/Wien 12th edn, 2002<br />

[Best Grauer 1991] Michael J. Best <strong>an</strong>d Robert R. Grauer (1991): On the<br />

Sensitivity of Me<strong>an</strong> Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Efficient Portfolios to Ch<strong>an</strong>ges in <strong>Asset</strong><br />

Me<strong>an</strong>s: Some Analytical <strong>an</strong>d Computational Results, Review of Fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

Studies, J<strong>an</strong>uary, 315-342<br />

[Bessembinder 1992] Hendrik Bessembinder (1992): Systematic Risk, Hedging<br />

Pressure <strong>an</strong>d Risk Premiums in Futures Markets, Review of Fin<strong>an</strong>cial<br />

Studies, vol. 5, no. 4 (Winter), 637-667<br />

[Bessembinder e.a. 1995] Hendrik Bessembinder, Jay F. Coughenour, Paul<br />

J. Seguin, Margaret Monroe Smoller (1995): Me<strong>an</strong> Reversion in<br />

Equilibrium <strong>Asset</strong> Pricing: Evidence from the Futures Term Structure,<br />

The Journal of Fin<strong>an</strong>ce, vol. 50, No. 1, 361-375<br />

[Black 1976] F. Black (1976): Studies of stock price volatility, Proceeding of the<br />

1976 Meetings of the Americ<strong>an</strong> Statistical Association, Business <strong>an</strong>d Economic<br />

Statistic Section, 177-181<br />

[Bowley 1920] A.L. Bowley (1920): Elements of Statistics, New York: Charles<br />

Scribner’s Sons<br />

[BP Report 2006] BP research (2006): BP statistical Review of World Energy<br />

June 2006, www.bp.com<br />

[Brenn<strong>an</strong> Schwartz 1985] M.J. Brenn<strong>an</strong> & E.S. Schwartz (1985): Eval-<br />

208


References<br />

uating Natural Resource Investments, Journal of Business, vol. 58,<br />

no. 2 (April), 135-157<br />

[Broecker 1995] Bröcker (1995): Analysis I, Spektrum Akademischer Verlag, 2.<br />

Auflage<br />

[Campbell 2000] John Y. Campbell (2000): Diversification: A bigger free lunch,<br />

Harvard <strong>University</strong>, working paper<br />

[C<strong>as</strong>s<strong>as</strong>us Collin-Dufresne 2005] Jaime C<strong>as</strong>s<strong>as</strong>us & Pierre Collin-Dufresne<br />

(2005): Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Convenience Yield Implied from Commodity Futures<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Interest Rates, Journal of Fin<strong>an</strong>ce, vol. LX, no. 5 (October),<br />

2283-2332<br />

[CBOT 2003] Chicago Board of Trade (2003): M<strong>an</strong>aged Futures: Portfolio<br />

Diversification Opportunities<br />

[Chopra Ziemba 1993] Vijay K. Chopra <strong>an</strong>d William T. Ziemba (1993): The<br />

effect of errors in me<strong>an</strong>s, vari<strong>an</strong>ces <strong>an</strong>d covari<strong>an</strong>ces on optimal portfolio<br />

choise, Journal of Portfolio M<strong>an</strong>agement, winter, 6-11<br />

[<strong>Commodities</strong> 2006] Der Spiegel (2006): Kampf um Rohstoffe, Spiegel Verlag,<br />

special edition vol. 5, 2006<br />

[Cootner 1990] Paul H. Cootner (1990): Returns to Speculators: Telser versus<br />

KeynesJournal of Political Economy, vol. 68, 396-404<br />

[Cortazar Schwartz 2003] G. Cortazar & Eduardo S. Schwartz (2003): Implementing<br />

a Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Model of Oil Futures Prices, Energy Economics,<br />

vol. 25, 215-238<br />

[Cox Ross Ingersoll 1981] John C. Cox, Stepahn A. Ross, Jonath<strong>an</strong> E. Ingersoll<br />

(1981): The Relation between Forward Prices <strong>an</strong>d Futures<br />

Prices Journal of Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Economics, No.9, 321-346<br />

[Crush Spread 2006] Chicago Board of Trade (2006): Trading the Hogs <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Cattle Spread<br />

[Deaves Kinsky 1995] Richard Deaves <strong>an</strong>d Itzhak Krinsky (1995): Do Futures<br />

Prices for <strong>Commodities</strong> Embody Risk Premiums? Journal of Futures<br />

Markets, vol. 15, no. 6 (September), 396-404<br />

[DeRiin Nijm<strong>an</strong> Veld 2000] Fr<strong>an</strong>s Roon, Theo R. Nijm<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d Chris Veld<br />

209


References<br />

(2000): Hedging Pressure Effects in Futures Markets, Journal of Fin<strong>an</strong>ce,<br />

vol. 55, no. 3 (June), 1437-56<br />

[DeRoon Nijm<strong>an</strong> 2001] Fr<strong>an</strong>s A. DeRoon <strong>an</strong>d Theo E. Nijm<strong>an</strong> (2001): Testing<br />

for Me<strong>an</strong>-Vari<strong>an</strong>ce Sp<strong>an</strong>ning: A Survey, Journal of Empirical Fin<strong>an</strong>ce,<br />

vol. 8, 111-155<br />

[Dickey Fuller 1979] D. Dickey & W. Fuller (1979): Distribution of the Estimators<br />

for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root, Journal of the<br />

Americ<strong>an</strong> Statistical Association, 74, 427-431<br />

[DJAIGCI 2006] Dow Jones Comp<strong>an</strong>y (2006): The Dow Jones AIG Commodity<br />

Index H<strong>an</strong>dbook, www.djindexes.com<br />

[Dorfleitner 2002] G. Dorfleitner (2002): Stetige versus diskrete Renditen -<br />

Überlegungen zur richtigen Verwendung in Theorie und Praxis, Kredit<br />

und Kapital, 2002(2), 216-241<br />

[Edwards Liew 1999] F.R. Edwards & J. Liew (1999): M<strong>an</strong>aged Commodity<br />

Fund, The Journal of Futures Makets, Vol.19, No.4, 377-411<br />

[Efron Tibshir<strong>an</strong>i 1993] Bradley Efron & Robert J. Tibshir<strong>an</strong>i (1993): An<br />

introduction to the Bootstrap, CRC Press, www.crcpress.com<br />

[EIA Outlook 2006] Energy Information Edministration (2006):<br />

Outlook 2006<br />

Energy<br />

[Erb Harvey 2006] Claude B. Erb & Campbell Harvey (2006): The strategic<br />

<strong>an</strong>d tactical value of commodity futures, Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Analysts Journal,<br />

vol. 62, no. 2<br />

[Fama French 1987] E.F. Fama & K.R. French (1987): Commodity futures<br />

prices: Some evidence on forec<strong>as</strong>t power, premiums <strong>an</strong>d the theory of<br />

storage, Journal of Business, 60, 55-73<br />

[Fama Schwert 1977] Eugene F. Fama & William Schwert (1977): <strong>Asset</strong> Returns<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Inflation, Journal of Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Econometrics, 5, 115-146<br />

[French 1983] Kenneth R. French (1983): A Comparison of Futures <strong>an</strong>d Forward<br />

Prices, Journal of Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Economics, No.12, 311-342<br />

[Fung Hiesh 1997] W. Fung & D.A. Hiesh (1997): Survivorship bi<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong>d investment<br />

style in the returns of CTAs, Journal of Portfolio M<strong>an</strong>agement,<br />

fall<br />

210


References<br />

[Gabillon 1995] J. Gabillon (1995): The Term Structure of Oil Futures Prices,<br />

M<strong>an</strong>aging Energy Risk, 1st ed. London Risk Publications, 29-38<br />

[Geer 2000] Robert J. Greer (2000): The Nature of Commodity Index Returns,<br />

The Journal of Alternative Investments<br />

[Germ<strong>an</strong> 2005] Hélyette Germ<strong>an</strong> (2005): <strong>Commodities</strong> <strong>an</strong>d Commodity Derivativess,<br />

John Wiley <strong>an</strong>d Sons Publications<br />

[Germ<strong>an</strong> Nguyen 2002] H. Germ<strong>an</strong> & V.N. Nguyen (2002): Soybe<strong>an</strong> inventory<br />

<strong>an</strong>d forward curves dynamics, ESSEC working paper, M<strong>an</strong>agement Science<br />

[Gibson Schwartz 1990] R. Gibson & E.S. Schwartz (1990): Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic convenience<br />

yield <strong>an</strong>d the pricing of oil contingent claims, Journal of fin<strong>an</strong>ce,<br />

45, 959-976<br />

[Gong Huber L<strong>an</strong>zinner 2006] Xi Gong, Michael Huber, Steffen L<strong>an</strong>zinner<br />

(2006): Investmentfonds versus Zertifikatstrukturen, Bachelor Arbeit, TU<br />

Augsburg<br />

[Gorton Rouwenhorst 2004] Gary Gorton & K.Geert Rouwenhorst (2004):<br />

Facts <strong>an</strong>d F<strong>an</strong>t<strong>as</strong>ies about Commodity Futures, Yale ICF Working Paper,<br />

no. 04-20<br />

[Greer 1978] Robert J. Greer (1978): Conservative <strong>Commodities</strong>: A Key Inflation<br />

Hedge, Journal of Portfolio M<strong>an</strong>agement<br />

[Greer 1997] Robert J. Greer (1997): What is <strong>an</strong> <strong>Asset</strong> Cl<strong>as</strong>s <strong>an</strong>yway?, Journal<br />

of Portfolio M<strong>an</strong>agement, vol. 23, 83-91<br />

[Groeneveld Meeden 1984] R.A. Groeneveld <strong>an</strong>d G. Meeden (1984): Me<strong>as</strong>uring<br />

Skewness <strong>an</strong>d Kurtosis, The Statistici<strong>an</strong>, vol. 33, 391-399<br />

[Hamilton 1994] James D. Hamilton (1994): Time Series Analysis, Princton <strong>University</strong><br />

Press<br />

[ICCO] International Cocoa Org<strong>an</strong>ization: http : \ \ www.icco.org<br />

[ICCO05] International Cocoa Org<strong>an</strong>ization: Determination of Cocoa<br />

Prices <strong>an</strong>d the Functioning of the World Cocoa Market<br />

[ICI 2006] Investment Comp<strong>an</strong>y Institute (2006): Fact book 2006<br />

[Ito 2004] Kiyosi Ito (2004): Stoch<strong>as</strong>tic Processes, Springer<br />

211


References<br />

[Kaldor 1939] N. Kalsor (1939): Speculation <strong>an</strong>d economic stability, The review<br />

of Economic Studies, No.7, 1-27,<br />

[K<strong>an</strong>ji 1999] Gopal K. K<strong>an</strong>ji (1999): 100 Statistical Tests, SAGE Publications,<br />

London<br />

[Kat Oomen 2006] Harry M. Kat <strong>an</strong>d Roel C.A. Oomen (2006): What every<br />

investor should know about commodities: Part I: univariate return <strong>an</strong>alysts,<br />

Alternative Investment Research, working paper # 0029<br />

[Kat Oomen 2006a] Harry M. Kat <strong>an</strong>d Roel C.A. Oomen (2006): What every<br />

investor should know about commodities: Part II: multivariate return<br />

<strong>an</strong>alysts, Alternative Investment Research, working paper # 0033<br />

[Keynes 1930] John M. Keynes (1930): A Treatise on Money, in: The applied<br />

theory of money, vol.2, (MacMilli<strong>an</strong>: London), 142-147<br />

[Kim White 2004] Tae-Hw<strong>an</strong>g Kim <strong>an</strong>d Halbert White (2004): More Robust<br />

Estimation of Skweness <strong>an</strong>d Kurtosis: Simulation <strong>an</strong>d Application to the<br />

S&P 500 Index, Fin<strong>an</strong>ce Research Letters, vol. 1, 56-73<br />

[Kolb 1996] Robert Kolb (1996): The systematic Risk of Futures Contracts, The<br />

Journal of Futures Markets, mboxvol. 16, no. 6 (1996), 631-654<br />

[Lautier 2005] Delohine Lautier (2005): Term Structure Models of Commodity<br />

Prices: A Review<br />

[Levin Wright 2006] World Gold Council (2006): Short-Run <strong>an</strong>d Long-Run<br />

Determin<strong>an</strong>ts of the Price of Gold<br />

[Lilliefors 1967] H. Lilliefors (1967): On the Kolmogorov-Smirnov test for normality<br />

with me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d vari<strong>an</strong>ce unknown, Journal of Americ<strong>an</strong> Statistical<br />

Association, vol. 62<br />

[Lloydes 1952] E.H. Lloyds (1952): Le<strong>as</strong>t squares estimation of location <strong>an</strong>d scale<br />

parameters using order statistics, Biometrika, vol. 39, 88-95<br />

[LME 2006] The London Metal Exch<strong>an</strong>ge (2006):<br />

Metal Exch<strong>an</strong>ge, www.lme.co.uk<br />

History of the London<br />

[ma-research 052006] M<strong>an</strong>aged Account Research, Inc. (2006): M<strong>an</strong>aged Account<br />

Monthly Report, www.ma-research.com, May 2006<br />

[Markert 2005] Viola Markert (2005): <strong>Commodities</strong> <strong>as</strong> <strong>Asset</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d Consumption<br />

212


References<br />

Goods: Implications for the Valuation of Commodity Futures, Dissertation,<br />

<strong>University</strong> St. Gallen<br />

[Markowitz 1952] Harry Markowitz (1952): Portfolio Selection, Journal of Fin<strong>an</strong>ce,<br />

vol. 7, 77-91<br />

[Merrill Lynch 2006] Merrill Lynch (2006): The ML Oil Return <strong>an</strong>d Income<br />

Strategy Index<br />

[Michaud 1998] Richard O. Michaud (1998):<br />

Boston: Harvard Business School<br />

Efficient <strong>Asset</strong> M<strong>an</strong>agement,<br />

[Molin Abdi 1998] Molin Abdi (1998): Lilliefors <strong>an</strong>d V<strong>an</strong> Soest’s test for normality<br />

[Molin Abdi 1998] P. Molin <strong>an</strong>d H. Abdi (1998): New Tables <strong>an</strong>d numerical<br />

approximation for the Kolmogorov-Smirnov / Lilliefors / V<strong>an</strong> Soest test<br />

of normality, <strong>University</strong> of Bourgogne, <strong>Technical</strong> Document<br />

[Moors 1988] J.J.A. Moors (1988): A Qu<strong>an</strong>tile Alternative for Kurtosis, The Statistici<strong>an</strong>,<br />

vol. 37, 25-32<br />

[Morg<strong>an</strong> 1992] J.P.Morg<strong>an</strong> & Co. Inc. (1992):<br />

Euromoney Publications, London<br />

Commodity Linked Fin<strong>an</strong>ce,<br />

[N<strong>as</strong>h Shrayer 2004] D<strong>an</strong>iel N<strong>as</strong>h <strong>an</strong>d Boris Shrayer (2004): Morg<strong>an</strong> St<strong>an</strong>ley<br />

Presentation, IQPC Conference on Portfolio Diversification with Commodity<br />

<strong>Asset</strong>s, London, 27 May 2004<br />

[Phillips 1987] P.C.B. Phillips (1987): Time Series Regression with a Unit Root<br />

Econometrica, No. 55, 227-301<br />

[PIMCO 2006] PIMCO (2006): Strategic <strong>Asset</strong> Allocation <strong>an</strong>d <strong>Commodities</strong><br />

[Pindyck 1994] Robert S. Pindyck (1994): Inventories <strong>an</strong>d the Short-Run Dynamics<br />

of Commodity Prices Journal of Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Economics, No. 25,<br />

141-159<br />

[Powell 2006] James L. Powell (2006): Aitken’s Generalized Le<strong>as</strong>t Squares, <strong>University</strong><br />

of California<br />

[Privolos Dunc<strong>an</strong> 1991] Theophilos Privolos & Ronald C. Dunc<strong>an</strong> (1991):<br />

Commodity Risk M<strong>an</strong>agement <strong>an</strong>d Fin<strong>an</strong>ce, Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press<br />

[Risknet 2006] risknet (2006): Burnt by Cont<strong>an</strong>go<br />

213


References<br />

[Roche 1993] Roche, Juli<strong>an</strong> (1993): Commodity Linked Derivatives, IFR Publishing,<br />

London<br />

[Rogers 2005] Jim Rogers (2005): Hot <strong>Commodities</strong>, R<strong>an</strong>dom House<br />

[Samuelson 1965] P.A. Samuelson (1965): Proof that properly <strong>an</strong>ticipated futures<br />

prices fluctuate r<strong>an</strong>domly, Industrial M<strong>an</strong>agement Review, 55: 1297-1338<br />

[Sawyer Sprinkle 2003] W. Charles Sawyer <strong>an</strong>d Richard L. Sprinkle<br />

(2003): International Economics, Pearson Education, Prentice Hall<br />

[Schneeweiss 2000] Thom<strong>as</strong> Schneeweiss (2000): The Benefits of M<strong>an</strong>aged Futures,<br />

working paper, Alternative Investment M<strong>an</strong>agement Association<br />

[Schneeweiss Spurgin 1996] Thom<strong>as</strong> Schneeweiss & Richard Spurgin (1996):<br />

Comparison of Commodity <strong>an</strong>d M<strong>an</strong>aged Futures Benchmark Indices,<br />

working paper, supported by Chicago Board of Trade <strong>an</strong>d <strong>University</strong> of<br />

M<strong>as</strong>sachusetts<br />

[Schwartz 1997] Eduardo S. Schwartz (1997): The stoch<strong>as</strong>tic behaviour of commodity<br />

prices: Implications for valuation <strong>an</strong>d hedging, Journal of Fin<strong>an</strong>ce,<br />

52(3), 33-51<br />

[Schwartz 1998] Eduardo S. Schwartz (1998): Valuing Long-Term Commodity<br />

<strong>Asset</strong>s, Fin<strong>an</strong>cial M<strong>an</strong>agement, vol. 27, no. 1 (Spring), 57-66<br />

[Schwartz Smith 2000] Eduardo S. Schwartz & James E. Smith (2000): Short<br />

Term Variations <strong>an</strong>d Long Term Dynamics in Commodity Prices, M<strong>an</strong>agement<br />

Science, vol. 56, no. 7(July), 893-911<br />

[Schwert 1981] William Schwert (1981): The Adjustment of Stock Prices to<br />

Information about Inflation, Journal of Fin<strong>an</strong>ce, 36, 15-29<br />

[Seam<strong>an</strong>s 2003] Richard F. Seam<strong>an</strong>s (2003): Commodity Indices - Overview <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Analysis<br />

[Shapiro Wilk 1965] S.S. Shapiro <strong>an</strong>d M.B. Wilk (1965): An <strong>an</strong>alysis of vari<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

test for normality (complete sample), Biometrika, vol. 52, 591<br />

[Silverm<strong>an</strong> 1992] B. W. Silverm<strong>an</strong> (1992): Density Estimation for Statistics <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Data Analysis, Chapm<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d Hall<br />

[Smith Kennison 1996] Kathleen T. Smith & Pam Kennison (1996): Commodity<br />

Derivatives <strong>an</strong>d Fin<strong>an</strong>ce, Euromoney Publications, London<br />

214


References<br />

[Structured Products 2006] Satyajit D<strong>as</strong> (2006): Structured Products Vol.2: Equity,<br />

Commodity, Credit <strong>an</strong>d New Markets, John Wiley <strong>an</strong>d Sons Publications<br />

[The CRB Commodity Yearbook 2005] CRB - Commodity Research Bureau<br />

(2005): The CRB Commodity Yearbook, John Wiley <strong>an</strong>d Sons Publications<br />

[Till 2000] Hilary Till (2000): Two Types of systematic returns available in the<br />

commodity futures markets, <strong>Commodities</strong> Now, September 2000<br />

[Till 2006] Hilary Till (2006): <strong>Commodities</strong> at the Cross-Roads: Where<br />

to Now?, EDHEC Risk <strong>an</strong>d <strong>Asset</strong> M<strong>an</strong>agement Research Centre,<br />

www.edhec-risk.com<br />

[Till Feldm<strong>an</strong> 2006] Hilary Till <strong>an</strong>d Barry Feldm<strong>an</strong> (2006): Separating the<br />

Wheat from the Chaff: Backwardation <strong>as</strong> the Long-Term Driver of Commodity<br />

Futures Perform<strong>an</strong>ce, Evidence from Soy, Corn <strong>an</strong>d Wheat Futures<br />

from 1950 to 2004, EDHEC Risk Publications, March 2006<br />

[Tsay 2002] Ruey S. Tsay (2002): Analysis of Fin<strong>an</strong>cial Time Series, John Wiley<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Sons Publications<br />

[UBS research 2005] UBS (2005): Rohstoffe<br />

[UBS research 2006] UBS (2006): Rohstoffe: Knappheit im Überfluss<br />

[USDA Grain 2006] United States Department of Agriculture (2006):<br />

Grain World Markets <strong>an</strong>d Trade<br />

[USDA Livestock 2006] United States Department of Agriculture (2006):<br />

Livestock World Markets <strong>an</strong>d Trade<br />

[USDA Oilseeds 2006] United States Department of Agriculture (2006):<br />

Oilseeds World Markets <strong>an</strong>d Trade<br />

[V<strong>an</strong> Soest 1967] J. V<strong>an</strong> Soest (1967): Some experimental results concerning tests<br />

of normality, Statistica Neerl<strong>an</strong>dica, vol. 21, 91-97<br />

[Williams Wright 1991] J.C. Williams & B.D. Wright (1991):<br />

Commodity Markets, Cambridge <strong>University</strong> Press<br />

Storage <strong>an</strong>d<br />

[Wilshire Research 2005] Thom<strong>as</strong> E. Toth (2005): Commodity Index Comparison,<br />

www.wilshire.com<br />

215


References<br />

[Working 1948] H. Working (1948): Theory of the inverse carrying Charge in<br />

Futures Markets Journal Farm Economics, No.30, 1-28<br />

[Working 1949] H. Working (1949): The Theory of the Price of Storage, Americ<strong>an</strong><br />

Review, No.39, 1254-1262<br />

[Zagst 2002] Rudi Zagst (2002): Interest Rate M<strong>an</strong>agement, Springer Fin<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

[Zagst e.a. 2006] Xi Gong, Michales Huber, Steffen L<strong>an</strong>zinner <strong>an</strong>d Rudi<br />

Zagst (2006): Zertifikate - Mehrwert für Privat<strong>an</strong>leger?, Kredtiwesen,<br />

No.22, 1235-1239<br />

216

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!