07.01.2015 Views

Fund liquidation, self-selection and look-ahead bias in the hedge ...

Fund liquidation, self-selection and look-ahead bias in the hedge ...

Fund liquidation, self-selection and look-ahead bias in the hedge ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Fund</strong> <strong>liquidation</strong>, <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong><br />

<strong>bias</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> fund <strong>in</strong>dustry<br />

October 9, 2006


wide range of empirical <strong>bias</strong>es hampers <strong>hedge</strong> fund databases. In this paper<br />

A<br />

we focus upon survival-related <strong>bias</strong>es <strong>and</strong> disentangle <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong>es<br />

to <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> of funds <strong>and</strong> due to fund term<strong>in</strong>ation. Self-<strong>selection</strong><br />

due<br />

because funds voluntarily report <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>in</strong>formation to data vendors<br />

arises<br />

may decide to stop do<strong>in</strong>g so. By extend<strong>in</strong>g exist<strong>in</strong>g methodology, we<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

persistence <strong>in</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> fund performance over <strong>the</strong> period 1994-2000,<br />

analyze<br />

<strong>in</strong>to account <strong>the</strong> above <strong>bias</strong>es. The results show that <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong>es<br />

tak<strong>in</strong>g<br />

due to <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> enforce each o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>and</strong> may lead<br />

overestimat<strong>in</strong>g expected returns by as much as 8% per year. Overall,<br />

to<br />

results are consistent with positive persistence <strong>in</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> fund returns at<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

Abstract<br />

horizons of two <strong>and</strong> four quarters.<br />

JEL-codes: G11, G23, G14


<strong>the</strong> last decade, <strong>the</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> fund <strong>in</strong>dustry has grown enormously.<br />

Dur<strong>in</strong>g<br />

funds differ from mutual funds <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>vestment vehicles by <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

Hedge<br />

of regulation 1 , with limited transparency <strong>and</strong> disclosure, <strong>and</strong> by <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

lack<br />

structure (see, e.g., Fung <strong>and</strong> Hsieh, 1997). For example, most<br />

<strong>in</strong>ternal<br />

funds try to achieve an absolute return target, irrespective of global<br />

<strong>hedge</strong><br />

movements, while <strong>hedge</strong> fund managers typically have <strong>in</strong>centive-<br />

market<br />

contracts. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, <strong>hedge</strong> funds have a broad flexibility <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

based<br />

of securities <strong>the</strong>y hold <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> type of positions <strong>the</strong>y take. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

type<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> funds are often confronted with lockup periods <strong>and</strong><br />

h<strong>and</strong>,<br />

notice periods. Such restrictions on withdrawals imply smaller<br />

redemption<br />

fluctuations, <strong>and</strong> give fund managers more freedom <strong>in</strong> sett<strong>in</strong>g up longterm<br />

cash<br />

or illiquid positions.<br />

non-st<strong>and</strong>ard features make <strong>hedge</strong> funds an <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

Their<br />

vehicle for <strong>in</strong>vestors with potential diversification benefits. A wide<br />

of academic papers exam<strong>in</strong>es <strong>hedge</strong> fund performance <strong>and</strong> its persistence.<br />

range 2 Both for <strong>the</strong> mutual fund <strong>in</strong>dustry (Sirri <strong>and</strong> Tufano, 1998) <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

fund <strong>in</strong>dustry (Agarwal, Daniel <strong>and</strong> Naik, 2004, Baquero <strong>and</strong> Verbeek,<br />

<strong>hedge</strong><br />

2006), it is reported that money flows chase past performance. Berk<br />

Green (2004) present a <strong>the</strong>oretical model that expla<strong>in</strong>s that persistence<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

be competed away by <strong>in</strong>vestors rationally shift<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir money <strong>in</strong> search<br />

can<br />

superior <strong>in</strong>vestments. In <strong>the</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> fund <strong>in</strong>dustry, however, <strong>the</strong> presence<br />

for<br />

liquidity restrictions that prevent <strong>in</strong>vestors to quickly shift <strong>the</strong>ir money<br />

of<br />

one fund to <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, may result <strong>in</strong> genu<strong>in</strong>e (short-run) persistence<br />

from<br />

if <strong>in</strong>vestors allocate <strong>the</strong>ir money accord<strong>in</strong>g to past performance (see<br />

even<br />

ter Horst <strong>and</strong> Verbeek, 2005).<br />

Baquero,<br />

this paper we analyze <strong>the</strong> persistence <strong>in</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> fund performance tak-<br />

In<br />

<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>toaccountanumberofpotentiallyimportant<strong>bias</strong>esthatarepresent<strong>in</strong><br />

funds databases (see Fung <strong>and</strong> Hsieh, 1997, or Ackermann, McEnally<br />

<strong>hedge</strong><br />

Ravenscraft, 1999) or are <strong>in</strong>duced by <strong>the</strong> employed methodology. Survivorship<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>bias</strong> (see, e.g. Brown et al., 1992, Brown, Goetzmann <strong>and</strong> Ibbot-<br />

1<br />

U.S. <strong>hedge</strong> funds are def<strong>in</strong>ed by <strong>the</strong>ir freedom from regularity controls of <strong>the</strong> Invest-<br />

Company Act of 1940.<br />

ment<br />

2<br />

e.g., Brown, Goetzmann <strong>and</strong> Ibbotson, 1999, Agarwal <strong>and</strong> Naik, 2000, Bares,<br />

See,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Gyger, 2003, Boyson <strong>and</strong> Cooper, 2004, Capocci <strong>and</strong> Hübner, 2004, Baquero,<br />

Gibson<br />

Horst <strong>and</strong> Verbeek, 2005, <strong>and</strong> Jagannathan, Malakhov <strong>and</strong> Novikov, 2006.<br />

ter<br />

1 Introduction<br />

1


1999) arises if <strong>in</strong>formation on defunct funds is unavailable <strong>and</strong> only <strong>the</strong><br />

son,<br />

of surviv<strong>in</strong>g funds is <strong>in</strong>vestigated. For <strong>hedge</strong> funds, this <strong>bias</strong><br />

performance<br />

more severe than <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> mutual fund <strong>in</strong>dustry due to <strong>the</strong> much higher<br />

is<br />

rate (about 14% per year for <strong>hedge</strong> funds versus about 5% per<br />

attrition<br />

for mutual funds); see Malkiel <strong>and</strong> Saha (2005). Survivorship <strong>bias</strong> can<br />

year<br />

by us<strong>in</strong>g a “survivorship-<strong>bias</strong>-free database” (see, e.g. Elton, Gru-<br />

avoided<br />

<strong>and</strong> Blake, 1996), which also <strong>in</strong>cludes (historical) <strong>in</strong>formation on funds<br />

ber<br />

are no longer active. However, when <strong>in</strong>vestigat<strong>in</strong>g performance or its<br />

that<br />

over multiple periods, this imposes <strong>the</strong> condition that fund returns<br />

persistence<br />

are available over a number of consecutive periods. For example, when<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r fund performance over two historical years persists <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestigat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

subsequent two years, only funds that survived <strong>and</strong> reported over a four<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

period are used <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> empirical analysis. This typically <strong>in</strong>troduces a<br />

year<br />

sampl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>bias</strong> or <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> (see, e.g. ter Horst, Nijman<br />

multi-period<br />

Verbeek, 2001), even if <strong>the</strong> database is “survivorship-<strong>bias</strong>-free”. This<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

focuses upon <strong>the</strong> importance of <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> <strong>and</strong> its underly<strong>in</strong>g<br />

paper<br />

causes.<br />

<strong>hedge</strong> funds are not allowed to advertise publicly, <strong>hedge</strong> fund data-<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ce<br />

(like TASS, MAR <strong>and</strong> HFR) serve as important distribution channels.<br />

bases<br />

report<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong>se databases is voluntary. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, <strong>hedge</strong><br />

However,<br />

may decide to start report<strong>in</strong>g after some <strong>in</strong>itial, successful period,<br />

funds<br />

enter a database with an <strong>in</strong>stant history. This process may lead to<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

upward <strong>bias</strong> <strong>in</strong> performance measures, referred to as <strong>in</strong>cubation <strong>bias</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

an<br />

<strong>bias</strong> (see, e.g., Posthuma <strong>and</strong> van der Sluis, 2003). Fur<strong>the</strong>r, funds<br />

backfill<strong>in</strong>g<br />

stop report<strong>in</strong>g for several reasons. Besides <strong>liquidation</strong> of <strong>the</strong> fund, fund<br />

may<br />

may stop report<strong>in</strong>g because underperformers do not wish to make<br />

managers<br />

performance known, because funds that performed well have less <strong>in</strong>centive<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir<br />

to report to data vendors to attract potential <strong>in</strong>vestors, or because<br />

may decide to change <strong>the</strong>ir report<strong>in</strong>g from one database to ano<strong>the</strong>r.<br />

funds<br />

is no consensus <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> literature on <strong>the</strong> term<strong>in</strong>ology for <strong>the</strong>se <strong>bias</strong>es<br />

There<br />

e.g., Jagannathan, Malakhov <strong>and</strong> Novikov, 2006). We will refer to <strong>the</strong><br />

(see,<br />

due to an endogenous decision of fund managers to stop report<strong>in</strong>g as<br />

<strong>bias</strong><br />

<strong>bias</strong> (or, more precisely, <strong>look</strong> <strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> due to <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>).<br />

<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong><br />

nonreport<strong>in</strong>g is related to fund <strong>liquidation</strong>, we refer to it as <strong>liquidation</strong><br />

When<br />

<strong>bias</strong>.<br />

recent study of persistence <strong>in</strong> performance of <strong>hedge</strong> funds of Baquero,<br />

A<br />

2


terHorst,<strong>and</strong>Verbeek(2005)f<strong>in</strong>dsthat<strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong><strong>bias</strong>dueto<strong>liquidation</strong><br />

affects <strong>the</strong> results <strong>and</strong> that correct<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong> is es-<br />

seriously<br />

For <strong>in</strong>stance, without correct<strong>in</strong>g for endogenous fund <strong>liquidation</strong>,<br />

sential.<br />

raw returns (with<strong>in</strong> a given rank<strong>in</strong>g decile) might be overestimated<br />

average<br />

as much as 5% when persistence is analyzed at an annual level. However,<br />

by<br />

Baquero, ter Horst <strong>and</strong> Verbeek (2005) it is assumed that <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong><br />

exogenous. If <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> would be ma<strong>in</strong>ly driven by good perform<strong>in</strong>g<br />

is<br />

that are closed to new <strong>in</strong>vestment, this may have a compensat<strong>in</strong>g im-<br />

funds<br />

upon performance <strong>and</strong> persistence measures, such that <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong><br />

pact<br />

<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong> offset each o<strong>the</strong>r. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r h<strong>and</strong>, if <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

negatively related to past performance, correct<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong><br />

is<br />

exacerbate <strong>the</strong> <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong> corrections <strong>and</strong> thus streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> re-<br />

may<br />

persistence patterns <strong>in</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> fund performance. Consequently, it is<br />

ported<br />

<strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g question to separately identify <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong><br />

an<br />

<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> fund persistence.<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

this paper we analyze <strong>the</strong> persistence <strong>in</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> fund performance<br />

In<br />

<strong>in</strong>to account both <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong>. The question<br />

tak<strong>in</strong>g<br />

past performance is <strong>in</strong>dicative of future performance has been ex-<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r<br />

studied for mutual funds. The results are somewhat mixed, but<br />

tensively<br />

general it can be concluded that <strong>the</strong>re is little evidence of performance<br />

<strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>hedge</strong> funds recent studies show some evidence<br />

For<br />

of short term performance persistence (see, e.g. Agarwal <strong>and</strong> Naik,<br />

Bares, Gibson <strong>and</strong> Gyger, 2003) while at longer horizons <strong>the</strong> results are<br />

2000,<br />

ambiguous (see, e.g., Brown, Goetzmann <strong>and</strong> Ibbotson, 1999, Brown<br />

more<br />

Goetzmann, 2003, Kosowski, Naik <strong>and</strong> Teo, 2006). None of <strong>the</strong>se studies<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

corrects for <strong>the</strong> possibility of <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong>. Baquero, ter Horst <strong>and</strong><br />

(2005) correct for <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> due to fund <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<br />

Verbeek<br />

persistence patterns <strong>in</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> fund performance, particularly at<br />

exacerbated<br />

annual horizon.<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

this paper we make a number of contributions to <strong>the</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> funds lit-<br />

In<br />

First, we empirically exam<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong> factors that affect <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong><br />

erature.<br />

by identify<strong>in</strong>g variables from reports supplied by data vendors. Inter-<br />

<strong>bias</strong><br />

past performance appears to have a significant <strong>and</strong> negative impact<br />

est<strong>in</strong>gly,<br />

<strong>the</strong> probability that a fund decides to stop report<strong>in</strong>g. That is, poorly<br />

upon<br />

3<br />

See, e.g., Carhart, 1997, ter Horst <strong>and</strong> Verbeek, 2000, Wermers, 2003, Bollen <strong>and</strong><br />

persistence of mutual funds. 3<br />

Busse, 2005, or Huij <strong>and</strong> Verbeek, 2006.<br />

3


funds are more likely to disappear from <strong>the</strong> TASS database at<br />

perform<strong>in</strong>g<br />

own request. Second, we propose a method that will correct for <strong>self</strong>-<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir<br />

<strong>bias</strong> separately from <strong>the</strong> <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> due to fund <strong>liquidation</strong>.<br />

<strong>selection</strong><br />

while disentangl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> effects of <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong><br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally,<br />

we analyze <strong>the</strong> persistence <strong>in</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> fund performance over various<br />

<strong>bias</strong>,<br />

us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> TASS database of <strong>hedge</strong> funds over <strong>the</strong> period 1994-<br />

horizons,<br />

The results <strong>in</strong>dicate that, <strong>in</strong> addition to <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong>, correct<strong>in</strong>g<br />

2000.<br />

Both<strong>bias</strong>eswork<strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong>samedirection<br />

for<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong><strong>bias</strong>isimportant.<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir comb<strong>in</strong>ed impact may result <strong>in</strong> overestimat<strong>in</strong>g expected returns<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

a given decile by as much as 7.7% per year. As a result, <strong>the</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g<br />

with<strong>in</strong><br />

persistence <strong>in</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> fund performance is streng<strong>the</strong>ned once one corrects<br />

of<br />

both <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong>es. At <strong>the</strong> annual horizon, <strong>the</strong><br />

for<br />

excess return on a w<strong>in</strong>ner m<strong>in</strong>us loser portfolio, based upon previousyearreturns,isapproximately10%<br />

expected<br />

when both <strong>bias</strong>es are corrected for,<br />

database, analyze fund attrition <strong>and</strong> relate it to <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong><strong>selection</strong>.<br />

TASS<br />

Moreover, we estimate probit specifications for both <strong>the</strong> liquida-<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> decisions. Section 3 expla<strong>in</strong>s how one can correction<br />

for <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> due to <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> when analyz<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> fund performance <strong>and</strong> how <strong>the</strong>se two <strong>bias</strong>es can be<br />

persistence<br />

Empirical results concern<strong>in</strong>g persistence at different horizons<br />

disentangled.<br />

presented <strong>in</strong> Section 4, while Section 5 conta<strong>in</strong>s some robustness checks.<br />

are<br />

Section 6 concludes.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally,<br />

data used <strong>in</strong> this paper are from TASS Management Limited <strong>and</strong> conta<strong>in</strong><br />

The<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation of 1797 <strong>hedge</strong> funds over <strong>the</strong> period 1994-2000, where we<br />

attention to funds report<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> US$. Although <strong>the</strong> TASS database<br />

restrict<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation of <strong>hedge</strong> funds s<strong>in</strong>ce 1979, we focus on <strong>the</strong> period 1994-<br />

conta<strong>in</strong>s<br />

for several reasons. First, <strong>in</strong>formation on “dead” funds is available only<br />

2000<br />

funds that disappeared s<strong>in</strong>ce 1994, <strong>and</strong> second, <strong>the</strong> number of funds be-<br />

for<br />

1994 is very small. As mentioned above, whe<strong>the</strong>r or not we observe<br />

fore<br />

for a given fund depends upon two ma<strong>in</strong> issues. First, <strong>the</strong> fund may<br />

returns<br />

without corrections.<br />

whileitisonly4.3%<br />

structure of this paper is as follows. In Section 2 we discuss <strong>the</strong><br />

The<br />

2 Liquidation <strong>and</strong> Self-<strong>selection</strong><br />

be liquidated. Second, if <strong>the</strong> fund is not liquidated, its management may<br />

4


to not report returns <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>formation to TASS. We refer to this<br />

prefer<br />

decision as <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>. Ano<strong>the</strong>r potential problem is backfill<strong>in</strong>g<br />

second<br />

or <strong>in</strong>stant history <strong>bias</strong> (see, e.g., Posthuma <strong>and</strong> Van der Sluis, 2003),<br />

<strong>bias</strong><br />

arises because when funds are <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> TASS database for <strong>the</strong><br />

which<br />

time, <strong>the</strong>y come with a history of several quarters. We take backfill<strong>in</strong>g<br />

first<br />

<strong>in</strong>to account by only us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation on a fund once its age exceeds<br />

<strong>bias</strong><br />

year. one<br />

provides some qualitative <strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>the</strong> reason why a fund<br />

TASS<br />

from <strong>the</strong>ir sample. For example, we f<strong>in</strong>d explanations like “This<br />

disappeared<br />

liquidated end of August 1996.”, “Due to <strong>the</strong> <strong>Fund</strong> Managers request<br />

fund<br />

fund has been taken off <strong>the</strong> database.”, or “This fund is closed for new<br />

this<br />

In order to disentangle <strong>the</strong> different <strong>selection</strong> processes, we<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments.”.<br />

construct a variable that conta<strong>in</strong>s a code for <strong>the</strong> disappearance reason.<br />

first<br />

used <strong>the</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g codes <strong>and</strong> scanned <strong>the</strong> reported disappearance records<br />

We<br />

<strong>the</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g expressions:<br />

for<br />

liquidated or closed down,<br />

1.<br />

at fund manager’s request,<br />

2.<br />

closed to new <strong>in</strong>vestors,<br />

3.<br />

closed (unknown), <strong>and</strong><br />

4.<br />

matured. 5.<br />

<strong>the</strong> 612 <strong>hedge</strong> funds that have disappeared from <strong>the</strong> TASS database<br />

From<br />

1994-2000, about half falls <strong>in</strong> category 1 <strong>and</strong> we classify this group<br />

dur<strong>in</strong>g<br />

(42 funds) with reasons 3 <strong>and</strong> 5 are classified as<br />

Cases<br />

For <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r reasons classification as ei<strong>the</strong>r liquidated or<br />

“<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>”.<br />

is less obvious. Some of <strong>the</strong> funds with disappearance reason<br />

<strong>self</strong>-selected<br />

use a negative formulation to motivate <strong>the</strong>ir removal from <strong>the</strong> database.<br />

2<br />

<strong>in</strong>stance “This fund has been removed at fund manager’s request <strong>and</strong><br />

For<br />

not be provid<strong>in</strong>g performance tables as <strong>the</strong> fund is too small.”, or “This<br />

will<br />

was requested to be taken off by <strong>the</strong> fund manager because <strong>the</strong>y felt<br />

fund<br />

TASS clients were not tak<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir fund!”. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly,<br />

that<br />

of <strong>the</strong> funds with disappearance reason 2 may stop report<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> f<strong>in</strong>al<br />

some<br />

periods lead<strong>in</strong>g up to <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>liquidation</strong> (see Ackermann, McEnally <strong>and</strong><br />

1999) <strong>and</strong> are more appropriately classified as “liquidated” or<br />

Ravenscraft,<br />

ra<strong>the</strong>r than “<strong>self</strong>-selected” 4 . In order to classify <strong>the</strong>se funds,<br />

“term<strong>in</strong>ated”<br />

4<br />

The result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>bias</strong> is sometimes referred to as “end-of-life <strong>bias</strong>”, see Malkiel <strong>and</strong> Saha<br />

as “liquidated”.<br />

(2005).<br />

5


also to classify funds that disappeared due to an unknown reason (reason<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

4), we evaluate <strong>the</strong> money flows of <strong>the</strong>se funds over <strong>the</strong> year preced<strong>in</strong>g<br />

attrition. We estimate money flows follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> procedure used by<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir<br />

Daniel <strong>and</strong> Naik (2003). Assum<strong>in</strong>g that flows take place at <strong>the</strong><br />

Agarwal,<br />

of quarter t +1, flows are measured as <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>in</strong> total assets under<br />

end<br />

of a fund between <strong>the</strong> start <strong>and</strong> end of quarter t +1, <strong>in</strong> excess<br />

management<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment return dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> quarter. Subsequently, we aggregate<br />

of<br />

money flows over <strong>the</strong> four last available quarters.<br />

<strong>the</strong>se<br />

general, it is difficult to p<strong>in</strong> down what exactly <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> means for<br />

In<br />

<strong>hedge</strong> funds <strong>and</strong> a variety of reasons may underlie a fund’s decision<br />

<strong>the</strong>se<br />

prefer to be transparent <strong>and</strong> accountable <strong>in</strong> our<br />

We<br />

<strong>and</strong> classify all funds that disappear (accord<strong>in</strong>g to TASS) “at<br />

classification<br />

fund manager’s request” (reason 2) or because of an unknown reason<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

4), by <strong>the</strong> sign of <strong>the</strong>ir cash flows dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> last year. <strong>Fund</strong>s <strong>in</strong> this<br />

(reason<br />

experienc<strong>in</strong>g negative cash flows are considered “liquidated”, while<br />

category<br />

with positive cash flows are considered “<strong>self</strong>-selected” 5 . Note that<br />

those<br />

we identify empirically as “<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>” only refers to <strong>the</strong> decision of<br />

what<br />

<strong>hedge</strong> fund to stop report<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> TASS database, conditional upon <strong>the</strong><br />

a<br />

that <strong>the</strong> fund started report<strong>in</strong>g at some po<strong>in</strong>t. It does not reflect <strong>the</strong><br />

fact<br />

decision of a fund to report to TASS or ano<strong>the</strong>r database vendor (e.g.<br />

<strong>in</strong>itial<br />

or to not report at all.<br />

HFR),<br />

<strong>the</strong> 612 cases disappear<strong>in</strong>g between 1994—2000, we classify 464<br />

From<br />

as be<strong>in</strong>g liquidated, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g 148 as “<strong>self</strong>-selected” out of <strong>the</strong><br />

(76%)<br />

database. The average quarterly return, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> last year of report<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

TASS<br />

funds that stop report<strong>in</strong>g voluntarily experience positive average<br />

surpris<strong>in</strong>gly,<br />

cash flows <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir f<strong>in</strong>al year but relatively low average returns. The<br />

of −0.51%, however, is not very precise. More detailed <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

estimate<br />

provided <strong>in</strong> Table 1, where we report <strong>the</strong> average quarterly returns <strong>and</strong><br />

is<br />

average quarterly net money flows for funds that <strong>self</strong>-select, liquidate or<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> sample period 1994 - 2000. For example, <strong>the</strong> first row<br />

survive<br />

that, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> first quarter of 1994, <strong>the</strong> average return of funds that<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicates<br />

before <strong>the</strong> end of our sample period is −2.33%, while it is −1.83%<br />

liquidated<br />

5<br />

We explore <strong>and</strong> discuss alternative classifications <strong>in</strong> Section 5 below.<br />

to stop report<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

−0.10% <strong>and</strong> −0.51%, respectively, while <strong>the</strong> average net flows are −5.21%<br />

is<br />

<strong>the</strong> liquidated funds <strong>and</strong> +24.10% for <strong>the</strong> <strong>self</strong>-selected funds. Somewhat<br />

for<br />

for funds that survived until 2000. The table clearly shows that funds that<br />

6


<strong>self</strong>-selected liquidated survivors<br />

Quarter<br />

net flow return net flow return net flow<br />

return<br />

94-I −1.54% 1.22% −2.33% 9.73% −1.83% 6.33%<br />

94-II 0.26% 2.23% 2.26% 8.27% 0.97% 8.71%<br />

94-III 1.19% 10.94% 0.07% 3.98% 2.27% 8.54%<br />

94-IV −1.15% −1.22% −1.32% 1.35% −0.73% 2.40%<br />

95-I 2.35% 4.10% 2.91% 5.46% 4.47% 12.92%<br />

95-II 2.44% 19.39% 1.84% 1.31% 5.11% 6.83%<br />

95-III 3.51% 2.37% 1.19% 0.73% 4.71% 7.18%<br />

95-IV 3.12% −1.30% 2.57% 3.79% 3.64% 1.60%<br />

96-I 4.00% 8.05% 1.37% 1.16% 3.32% 8.39%<br />

96-IV 5.01% 4.12% 3.76% 8.76% 6.68% 14.63%<br />

97-I 3.43% 33.03% 4.60% 11.87% 4.32% 13.79%<br />

97-II 3.09% 6.97% 3.57% 2.99% 5.35% 12.14%<br />

97-III 4.14% 16.56% 6.14% 11.30% 7.83% 15.64%<br />

97-IV −2.56% −0.94% −2.38% −5.00% −0.50% 5.75%<br />

98-I 2.94% 18.32% 1.12% 3.03% 5.73% 19.48%<br />

98-II −5.73% 47.18% −3.21% −2.09% −0.66% 9.76%<br />

98-III −3.14% 11.63% −5.64% 0.82% −4.98% 2.63%<br />

98-IV −2.93% 23.97% 0.65% 0.29% 5.85% 9.14%<br />

99-III −0.99% 11.38% −1.75% −10.11% 0.69% −3.29%<br />

99-IV 12.85% 22.14% −0.25% −3.67% 13.36% 17.20%<br />

average (unweighted) 1.62% 13.99% 0.95% 2.16% 3.59% 9.07%<br />

average (weighted) 1.58% 12.01% 1.30% 2.85% 3.98% 9.14%<br />

1: Average quarterly returns <strong>and</strong> net money flows of US <strong>hedge</strong> funds<br />

Table<br />

<strong>the</strong> TASS database that <strong>self</strong>-select, liquidate or survive dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> sample<br />

<strong>in</strong><br />

4.79% 4.66% 5.64% 13.07% 6.06% 11.40%<br />

96-II<br />

1.84% 3.59% 0.92% −1.18% 2.25% 14.04%<br />

96-III<br />

−0.10% 87.28% −1.25% −9.88% 3.70% 2.96%<br />

99-I<br />

2.06% 0.16% 2.30% −4.15% 8.45% 9.48%<br />

99-II<br />

00-I − − − − 5.96% 0.81%<br />

1994-2000. The row labeled ‘average (weighted)’ reports <strong>the</strong> weighted<br />

period<br />

(weighted by <strong>the</strong> number of funds per quarter) over <strong>the</strong> sample pe-<br />

averages<br />

riod, while <strong>the</strong> row ‘average (unweighted)’ reports <strong>the</strong> unweighted averages.<br />

7


dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> sample period have substantial lower average returns<br />

liquidate<br />

net money flows than funds that <strong>self</strong>-select or survive. The average<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

for funds that liquidate is about 0.95% per quarter, while funds that<br />

return<br />

or survive have an average quarterly return of 1.62% <strong>and</strong> 3.59%,<br />

<strong>self</strong>-select<br />

The average quarterly net money flows exhibit a similar pattern.<br />

respectively.<br />

<strong>Fund</strong>s that liquidate have an average quarterly net money flow of only<br />

while funds that <strong>self</strong>-select or survive have an average net money<br />

2.16%,<br />

of 13.99% <strong>and</strong> 9.07%, respectively. Comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> three subsamples<br />

flow<br />

are about 2.1% (per annum) higher than <strong>the</strong> average return of <strong>the</strong><br />

funds<br />

samples. This number is usually referred to as survivorship <strong>bias</strong><br />

comb<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

e.g. Malkiel, 1995 <strong>and</strong> Liang, 2000). The <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong> is def<strong>in</strong>ed as<br />

(see,<br />

difference between <strong>the</strong> average returns of <strong>the</strong> comb<strong>in</strong>ation of <strong>the</strong> sub-<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

of <strong>self</strong>-selected <strong>and</strong> surviv<strong>in</strong>g funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> comb<strong>in</strong>ation of all three<br />

samples<br />

This <strong>bias</strong> is about 2.0% (per annum) (see, e.g. Baquero, ter<br />

subsamples.<br />

<strong>and</strong> Verbeek, 2005). F<strong>in</strong>ally, we can def<strong>in</strong>e <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong> as <strong>the</strong><br />

Horst<br />

between <strong>the</strong> subsamples of liquidated <strong>and</strong> surviv<strong>in</strong>g funds <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

difference<br />

of all three subsamples. This <strong>bias</strong> is about 0.8% (per annum).<br />

comb<strong>in</strong>ation<br />

our <strong>in</strong>terest lies <strong>in</strong> persistence at horizons of at least one quarter,<br />

Because<br />

aggregate all <strong>in</strong>formation to quarterly levels. This has <strong>the</strong> advantage of<br />

we<br />

<strong>the</strong> impact of return smooth<strong>in</strong>g due to <strong>the</strong> possibility that a <strong>hedge</strong><br />

reduc<strong>in</strong>g<br />

liquidated <strong>in</strong> quarter t (L it =1o<strong>the</strong>rwise). Given that a fund is not<br />

has<br />

returns may not be available due to <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>, <strong>and</strong> we let<br />

liquidated,<br />

S it = 0if fund i attrited <strong>the</strong> database because of <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> (S it = 1<br />

both decisions we specify a b<strong>in</strong>ary choice model. First, <strong>the</strong> <strong>liquidation</strong><br />

For<br />

decision is modelled by means of a b<strong>in</strong>ary probit model, with latent<br />

L ∗ it = α 1 +<br />

6∑<br />

an average quarterly return <strong>and</strong> net money flow of 3.06% <strong>and</strong> 7.78%,<br />

gives<br />

(not reported). Note that <strong>the</strong> average returns of <strong>the</strong> surviv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

respectively<br />

<strong>in</strong>vests <strong>in</strong> securities that are not actively traded (see Getmansky, Lo<br />

fund<br />

Makarov, 2004). Consequently, we also analyze <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

at <strong>the</strong> quarterly level. In <strong>the</strong> rema<strong>in</strong>der of <strong>the</strong> paper <strong>liquidation</strong><br />

<strong>selection</strong><br />

be denoted by an <strong>in</strong>dicator variable L, suchthat L it = 0if fund i<br />

will<br />

o<strong>the</strong>rwise). This implies that a return r it is observed only if L it S it =1.<br />

variable equation<br />

γ 1j<br />

r i,t−j<br />

+ x ′ it β 1 + ε 1,it, (1)<br />

j=1<br />

8


mean std.dev m<strong>in</strong> max<br />

Variable<br />

0.59 0.49 0 1<br />

offshore<br />

Fees 15.87 7.82 0 50<br />

Incentive<br />

Fees 1.63 1.08 0 8<br />

Mng.<br />

0.14 0.34 0 1<br />

Underwater<br />

16.73 1.79 7.58 23.30<br />

ln(NAV)<br />

3.80 0.66 2.56 5.62<br />

ln(Age) 2 14.89 5.09 6.58 31.55<br />

ln(Age)<br />

x it<br />

where<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicator satisfies L it<br />

=0(<strong>liquidation</strong>) if L ∗ it<br />

observed<br />

decision. It is assumed that ε 1,it<br />

<strong>liquidation</strong><br />

variables. We expect that γ explanatory 1j<br />

we specify a process for <strong>the</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> decision as a probit<br />

Similarly,<br />

based on<br />

model<br />

6∑<br />

S it =0(<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>) if S ∗ it<br />

with<br />

variables x it<br />

condition<strong>in</strong>g<br />

both equations is <strong>in</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciple <strong>the</strong> same, a priori<br />

<strong>in</strong><br />

restrictions may be imposed.<br />

exclusion<br />

Table 2 we present some summary statistics of <strong>the</strong> fund-specific variables<br />

In<br />

(x it<br />

) that were <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> models.<br />

appears It<br />

59% of <strong>the</strong> observations are from offshore <strong>hedge</strong> funds. These funds,<br />

that<br />

report<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> US$, are located <strong>in</strong> tax-havens like <strong>the</strong> Virg<strong>in</strong> Isl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

while<br />

average <strong>in</strong>centive fee of <strong>the</strong> fund manager is about 16%, butcanbe<br />

The<br />

high as 50% of realized performance. Note that <strong>the</strong>se <strong>in</strong>centive fees are<br />

as<br />

obta<strong>in</strong>ed when <strong>the</strong> fund has recovered past losses (high water-mark).<br />

only<br />

StDev 0.08 0.08 0.00 1.63<br />

Table 2: Summary statistics fund-specific variables.<br />

(20138 fund/period<br />

observations)<br />

denotes a vector of fund characteristics that affect <strong>liquidation</strong>. The<br />

0 <strong>and</strong> 1o<strong>the</strong>rwise.<br />

<<br />

specification allows fund returns up to six quarters ago to affect <strong>the</strong><br />

The<br />

is IIN(0, 1), <strong>in</strong>dependent of <strong>the</strong><br />

0 for several of <strong>the</strong> lags, so<br />

><br />

<strong>the</strong> better perform<strong>in</strong>g funds are, ceteris paribus, less likely to liquidate.<br />

that<br />

S ∗ it = α 2 +<br />

γ 2j<br />

r i,t−j<br />

+ x ′ it β 2 + ε 2,it, (2)<br />

j=1<br />

< 0 <strong>and</strong> 1o<strong>the</strong>rwise. While <strong>the</strong> set of<br />

of <strong>the</strong>se variable also appear <strong>in</strong> related specifications of Brown, Goetzmann<br />

Most<br />

<strong>and</strong> Park (2001) <strong>and</strong> Baquero, ter Horst <strong>and</strong> Verbeek (2005). Summary<br />

statistics are based on 20138 fund/period observations.<br />

The annual management fee varies between 0% <strong>and</strong> 8% (of net asset value)<br />

9


has an average of 1.6%. The underwater <strong>in</strong>dicator is equal to one if a<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

has a negative cumulative return over <strong>the</strong> past eight quarters 6 ,which<br />

fund<br />

<strong>in</strong> 14% of <strong>the</strong> cases. The age of <strong>the</strong> funds varies between 13 months<br />

occurs<br />

275 months (about 23 years), while <strong>the</strong> average age is about 45 months.<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

average size of <strong>the</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> funds, measured by <strong>the</strong>ir log net asset value<br />

The<br />

to about 18 million US$. Total risk is measured by <strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

corresponds<br />

of <strong>the</strong> previous six quarterly returns (StDev).<br />

deviation<br />

size (NAV) is not available for each quarter for all funds <strong>in</strong> our<br />

<strong>Fund</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> models us<strong>in</strong>g two specifications,<br />

estimated<br />

<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g size (based on 20138 fund/period observations) <strong>and</strong> one ex-<br />

one<br />

size (based on 21297 fund/period observations). Follow<strong>in</strong>g Baquero,<br />

clud<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Horst <strong>and</strong> Verbeek (2005) we employ <strong>the</strong> TASS <strong>in</strong>vestment style clas-<br />

ter<br />

which is closely related to <strong>the</strong> 9 commonly used Tremont <strong>hedge</strong><br />

sification,<br />

style <strong>in</strong>dices 7 . In Table 3 we report <strong>the</strong> estimation results based on<br />

fund<br />

20138 fund/period observations for <strong>the</strong> probit specification for <strong>liquidation</strong><br />

that non-<strong>liquidation</strong> means<br />

Note<br />

it is still possible that <strong>the</strong> fund <strong>self</strong>-selected dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> sample period.<br />

that<br />

we subsequently remove all <strong>the</strong> fund/period observations where<br />

Therefore,<br />

fund liquidated (417 fund/period observations) <strong>and</strong> estimate <strong>the</strong> probit<br />

a<br />

to expla<strong>in</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> versus survival (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g size), where<br />

specification<br />

implies that <strong>the</strong> fund did not liquidate <strong>and</strong> still prefers to report<br />

survival<br />

performance to <strong>the</strong> data vendor. The estimation results are reported<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir<br />

Table 4. The estimation results for both specifications exclud<strong>in</strong>g size are<br />

<strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> appendix (Table 9 <strong>and</strong> Table 10). All models <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

reported<br />

style dummies, while time dummies are <strong>in</strong>cluded to capture aggregate<br />

to <strong>the</strong> probabilities of <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>. The <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

shocks<br />

“convertible arbitrage” <strong>and</strong> “dedicated short <strong>bias</strong>” conta<strong>in</strong> very lim-<br />

styles<br />

6 The cumulative return is determ<strong>in</strong>ed over at least five quarters with a maximum of<br />

quarters.<br />

7 eight<br />

has <strong>the</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g n<strong>in</strong>e <strong>hedge</strong> fund <strong>in</strong>vestment styles: Convertible Arbitrage,<br />

Tremont<br />

Short Bias, Emerg<strong>in</strong>g Markets, Equity Market Neutral, Event Driven, Fixed<br />

Dedicated<br />

Arbitrage, Global Macro, Long/Short Equity, Managed Futures, <strong>and</strong> Hedge <strong>Fund</strong><br />

Income<br />

Therefore, we use <strong>the</strong> most recent observation of net asset value<br />

sample.<br />

from <strong>the</strong> TASS database. However, <strong>the</strong>re rema<strong>in</strong> some observa-<br />

available<br />

for which NAV is miss<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> cannot be imputed. This occurs <strong>in</strong> 7%<br />

tions<br />

<strong>the</strong> cases. Because we do not want to elim<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>the</strong>se observations, we<br />

of<br />

versus non-<strong>liquidation</strong> (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g size).<br />

Index.<br />

10


0.220 0.227 emerg<strong>in</strong>g markets −0.154 0.080<br />

r(−4)<br />

0.029 0.207 equity market neutral −0.191 0.092<br />

r(−5)<br />

3: Estimation results <strong>liquidation</strong> model, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g net asset value<br />

Table<br />

20138 fund/period observations.<br />

(size);<br />

no dummies are <strong>in</strong>cluded for <strong>the</strong>se<br />

Accord<strong>in</strong>gly,<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>se funds are implicitly allocated to <strong>the</strong> general <strong>hedge</strong> fund<br />

styles,<br />

(reference category). The coefficient estimates for <strong>the</strong> time dummies<br />

<strong>in</strong>dex<br />

available upon request.<br />

are<br />

specification (3), <strong>the</strong> first three past quarterly returns have a significant<br />

In<br />

impact on <strong>the</strong> <strong>liquidation</strong> decision, while <strong>in</strong> specification (4) only <strong>the</strong><br />

two past quarterly returns are statistically significant. The cumulative<br />

first<br />

of <strong>the</strong> first three lagged returns <strong>in</strong> both models is about <strong>the</strong> same.<br />

impact<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>liquidation</strong> model, positive coefficients <strong>in</strong>dicate that higher historical<br />

In<br />

imply a lower probability to liquidate. In <strong>the</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> model,<br />

returns<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicate that funds with high historical returns are more likely to survive,<br />

<strong>the</strong>y<br />

where surviv<strong>in</strong>g means that <strong>the</strong> fund did not liquidate <strong>and</strong> decides to<br />

report<strong>in</strong>g to TASS. However, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>liquidation</strong> model an additional<br />

keep<br />

of historical returns is captured by <strong>the</strong> underwater <strong>in</strong>dicator, which<br />

impact<br />

highly significant. The negative coefficient implies that if a fund has a<br />

is<br />

aggregate return over <strong>the</strong> most recent eight quarters, it is signifi-<br />

negative<br />

more likely to liquidate. That is, if a fund is underwater, imply<strong>in</strong>g<br />

cantly<br />

<strong>the</strong> manager will not receive <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centive fee, <strong>the</strong> probability of liqui-<br />

that<br />

<strong>in</strong>creases substantially, potentially due to excessive risk-tak<strong>in</strong>g (compardation<br />

Goetzmann, Ingersoll <strong>and</strong> Ross, 2003). For <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>, <strong>the</strong> impact<br />

Parameters Estimate Std.error Parameters Estimate Std. Error<br />

<strong>in</strong>tercept 1.984 0.763 offshore −0.136 0.051<br />

r(−1) 1.182 0.214 Incentive Fees −0.008 0.003<br />

r(−2) 0.802 0.222 Mng. Fees −0.012 0.024<br />

r(−3) 1.058 0.223 underwater −0.245 0.066<br />

r(−6) 0.103 0.221 event driven 0.083 0.107<br />

ln(NAV) 0.155 0.015 fixed <strong>in</strong>come arbitrage −0.180 0.202<br />

StDev 1.182 0.370 global macro −0.164 0.176<br />

ln(Age) −0.617 0.379 long/short equity −0.160 0.075<br />

ln(Age) 2 0.087 0.050 managed futures −0.075 0.071<br />

Loglikelihood: −1729.338 Chi-squared test: 600.28 (DF =42)<br />

pseudoR 2 : 0.148 (p =0.000)<br />

ited numbers of funds.<br />

of be<strong>in</strong>g underwater seems negligible, both economically <strong>and</strong> statistically.<br />

11


0.732 0.374 emerg<strong>in</strong>g markets −0.068 0.133<br />

r(−4)<br />

−0.130 0.326 equity market neutral 0.023 0.148<br />

r(−5)<br />

4: Estimation results <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> model, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g net asset value<br />

Table<br />

19721 fund/period observations.<br />

(size);<br />

<strong>the</strong> results <strong>in</strong> Tables 3 <strong>and</strong> 4 <strong>in</strong>dicate that <strong>the</strong> impact of historical<br />

Overall,<br />

is somewhat stronger for <strong>the</strong> <strong>liquidation</strong> decision than for <strong>the</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<br />

returns<br />

decision. The impact of size (ln(NAV)) is significantly positive, i.e.<br />

<strong>selection</strong><br />

funds have a higher probability to liquidate or <strong>self</strong>-select than larger<br />

smaller<br />

(ceteris paribus).<br />

funds<br />

results for <strong>the</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> model are clearly at odds with <strong>the</strong> idea<br />

The<br />

good perform<strong>in</strong>g funds are more likely to stop report<strong>in</strong>g because <strong>the</strong>y<br />

that<br />

longer wish to attract new <strong>in</strong>vestors. Also, it does not appear to be <strong>the</strong><br />

no<br />

that large funds, which may suffer most from decreas<strong>in</strong>g returns to scale<br />

case<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir <strong>in</strong>vestment strategies, are more likely to voluntary stop report<strong>in</strong>g be-<br />

of<br />

managers are unwill<strong>in</strong>g to attract new money. Total risk, as measured<br />

cause<br />

<strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation over <strong>the</strong> past six quarters, significantly affects<br />

by<br />

<strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> decision positively, imply<strong>in</strong>g that high risk<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

funds have a higher probability to survive. This seems a counter<strong>in</strong>tu-<br />

<strong>hedge</strong><br />

result, <strong>and</strong> apparently contradicts <strong>the</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs of Brown, Goetzmann<br />

itive<br />

Park (2001) who f<strong>in</strong>d that high risk funds have a higher probability to<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

However, our results suggest that high risk funds experience a<br />

liquidate.<br />

lower <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> probability, given <strong>the</strong> return<br />

somewhat<br />

<strong>and</strong> fund size. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, <strong>the</strong>y <strong>in</strong>dicate that high risk funds are<br />

history<br />

to have more extreme negative returns than low risk funds before<br />

allowed<br />

Parameters Estimate Std.error Parameters Estimate Std. Error<br />

<strong>in</strong>tercept 2.915 1.163 offshore 0.093 0.076<br />

r(−1) 1.393 0.357 Incentive Fees −0.013 0.005<br />

r(−2) 1.289 0.366 Mng. Fees −0.035 0.036<br />

r(−3) 0.445 0.340 underwater 0.083 0.116<br />

r(−6) 0.657 0.389 event driven 0.118 0.150<br />

ln(NAV) 0.093 0.023 fixed <strong>in</strong>come arbitrage 0.019 0.366<br />

StDev 1.414 0.622 global macro 0.202 0.357<br />

ln(Age) −0.719 0.591 long/short equity −0.148 0.108<br />

ln(Age) 2 0.102 0.078 managed futures 0.058 0.111<br />

Loglikelihood: −658.876 Chi-squared test: 135.78 (DF =42)<br />

pseudoR 2 : 0.093 (p =0.000)<br />

<strong>the</strong>y decide to liquidate or <strong>self</strong>-select (see Baquero, ter Horst <strong>and</strong> Verbeek,<br />

12


2005).<br />

both specifications, age has a significant nonl<strong>in</strong>ear impact, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

In<br />

old funds with past poor performance are less likely to disappear than<br />

that<br />

funds with a similar poor performance. This f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g corresponds<br />

young<br />

<strong>the</strong> results of Boyson <strong>and</strong> Cooper (2004), who perform unconditional<br />

to<br />

conditional survival tests, <strong>and</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ds that age <strong>and</strong> manager ability are<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

related to <strong>the</strong> likelihood of a manager’s survival. Offshore funds<br />

positively<br />

a larger probability to liquidate than onshore funds, while given that<br />

have<br />

fund did not liquidate, be<strong>in</strong>g an offshore fund does not significantly<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> decision. The impact of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centive fee on <strong>the</strong><br />

affect<br />

probability or survival probability is significantly negative,<br />

non-<strong>liquidation</strong><br />

a higher <strong>in</strong>centive fee, ceteris paribus, <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>the</strong> probability that a<br />

i.e.<br />

will liquidate or <strong>self</strong>-select. The significant coefficient estimates for <strong>the</strong><br />

fund<br />

style dummies ‘equity market neutral’ <strong>and</strong> ‘long/short equity’<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>liquidation</strong> model <strong>in</strong>dicate, ceteris paribus, that <strong>the</strong>se styles have a<br />

<strong>in</strong><br />

probability to liquidate. The impact of <strong>in</strong>vestment styles on <strong>the</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<br />

higher<br />

decision is <strong>in</strong>significant, although most of <strong>the</strong> coefficient estimates<br />

<strong>selection</strong><br />

positive <strong>in</strong> contrast to <strong>the</strong> estimates for <strong>the</strong> <strong>liquidation</strong> model.<br />

are<br />

results show that most of <strong>the</strong> factors <strong>in</strong> our specifications affect<br />

Our<br />

<strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> decisions <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> same direction. Given<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

importance of past performance, we conclude that <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> is not<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

Consequently, it can be expected that <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong>es due to<br />

exogenous.<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>liquidation</strong> will not offset, but even streng<strong>the</strong>n each o<strong>the</strong>r,<br />

<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong><br />

correct<strong>in</strong>g for both <strong>bias</strong>es will be necessary. In <strong>the</strong> next section, we<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

how both <strong>bias</strong>es can be disentangled <strong>and</strong> how persistence analyses<br />

describe<br />

be corrected for <strong>the</strong>se <strong>bias</strong>es. This can be achieved us<strong>in</strong>g an extension<br />

can<br />

<strong>in</strong>terest lies <strong>in</strong> analyz<strong>in</strong>g fund performance over <strong>the</strong> period t +1 to<br />

Suppose<br />

+ s +1, conditional upon a given <strong>in</strong>formation set Ω t<br />

. In some applications,<br />

t<br />

of <strong>the</strong> methodology reported <strong>in</strong> ter Horst, Nijman <strong>and</strong> Verbeek (2001).<br />

3 Disentangl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong><br />

<strong>bias</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>formation set may be empty. In o<strong>the</strong>rs, Ω t<br />

will conta<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dicators<br />

this<br />

<strong>the</strong> fund’s <strong>in</strong>vestment style <strong>and</strong> its previous performance (e.g. its per-<br />

for<br />

formance decile dur<strong>in</strong>g a rank<strong>in</strong>g period). This means that <strong>in</strong>terest lies <strong>in</strong><br />

13


conditional distribution of returns r i,t+1,...,r i,t+s+1<br />

given Ω t<br />

, which we<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

by denote<br />

f (r i,t+1, ..., r i,t+s+1|Ω t<br />

), (3)<br />

f is generic notation for a (conditional) density function. Empirically,<br />

where<br />

can only obta<strong>in</strong> full <strong>in</strong>formation about this jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution if <strong>the</strong> fund<br />

we<br />

us denote this by Y it<br />

f(r i,t+1,...,r i,t+s+1|Ω t<br />

,Y it<br />

=1). (4)<br />

(3) <strong>and</strong> (4) are identical, <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> is exogenous <strong>and</strong><br />

If<br />

<strong>bias</strong>es arise if <strong>the</strong> sample <strong>selection</strong> process is ignored. However, as we<br />

no<br />

seen <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> previous sections, it is likely that both <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong><strong>selection</strong><br />

have<br />

are determ<strong>in</strong>ed by historical performance <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r characteristics<br />

may have a relation with returns dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> period t +1 to t+s+1. For<br />

that<br />

funds that have high levels of (idiosyncratic) risk are more likely<br />

example,<br />

have extreme returns <strong>and</strong> are typically less likely to survive (see Brown et<br />

to<br />

1992, or Hendricks, Patel <strong>and</strong> Zeckhauser, 1997). The difference between<br />

al.,<br />

Theroleofz it<br />

has not liquidated or <strong>self</strong>-selected dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> period t +1to t + s +1. Let<br />

=1. This means we can empirically identify<br />

<strong>and</strong> (4) drives <strong>the</strong> <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> <strong>in</strong> performance measures.<br />

(3)<br />

distribution of <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> (3) can be derived from <strong>the</strong> jo<strong>in</strong>t distribu-<br />

The<br />

of r i,t+1, ..., r i,t+s+1<br />

<strong>and</strong> z it<br />

, conditional upon Ω t<br />

<strong>and</strong> Y it<br />

=1,wherez it<br />

tion<br />

a vector of observable fund characteristics <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r variables that<br />

denotes<br />

are relevant for fund <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> from t +1to t + s +1.<br />

will become clear below. First, note that<br />

i,t+1,...,.r<br />

i,t+s+1,z<br />

it<br />

|Ω t<br />

,Y it<br />

=1)= f(r i,t+1,...,r i,t+s+1,z it<br />

,Y it<br />

=1|Ω t<br />

)<br />

f(r<br />

{Y it<br />

=1|Ω t<br />

}<br />

P<br />

P {Y it<br />

=1|r i,t+1, ..., r i,t+s+1,z it<br />

, Ω t<br />

}f (r i,t+1, ..., r i,t+s+1,z it<br />

|Ω t<br />

)<br />

=<br />

{Y it =1|Ω t }<br />

P<br />

(5)<br />

f i,t+1, ..., r i,t+s+1,z it<br />

|Ω t<br />

)<br />

= ,<br />

(r<br />

it w<br />

where<br />

P {Y it =1|Ω t }<br />

(6)<br />

w it<br />

=<br />

P {Y it =1|r i,t+1, ..., r i,t+s+1, Ω t ,z it }<br />

14


<strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>tegral is over <strong>the</strong> support of z it<br />

. In this expression, <strong>the</strong> weight<br />

where<br />

w it<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicates how <strong>the</strong> distribution, conditional upon Y it<br />

=1can be<br />

factor<br />

only through z it (which may conta<strong>in</strong> historical returns <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r fund<br />

but<br />

<strong>the</strong> weights can be identified. In this case, <strong>the</strong> weights<br />

characteristics),<br />

that <strong>in</strong> general <strong>the</strong>se weights are endogenous, as z it will not be <strong>in</strong>dependent<br />

Note<br />

of r i,t+1,...,r i,t+s+1. This approach to solve <strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong> problems<br />

that a set of (observable) explanatory variables z it can be chosen<br />

assumes<br />

that, conditional upon z it , <strong>selection</strong> is <strong>in</strong>dependent of current <strong>and</strong> fu-<br />

such<br />

potentially unobserved, returns. This is referred to as “<strong>selection</strong> upon<br />

ture,<br />

<strong>and</strong> is employed <strong>in</strong>, e.g., Fitzgerald, Gottschalk <strong>and</strong> Moffitt<br />

observables”<br />

to correct for attrition <strong>bias</strong> from <strong>the</strong> Panel Study of Income Dynamics,<br />

(1998)<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> ter Horst, Nijman <strong>and</strong> Verbeek (2001) to elim<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong> evaluat<strong>in</strong>g persistence <strong>in</strong> mutual fund performance.<br />

<strong>bias</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> current application, Y it<br />

= 1implies that <strong>the</strong> fund has not liq-<br />

In<br />

dur<strong>in</strong>g t +1 to t + s +1 <strong>and</strong> has not stopped report<strong>in</strong>g due to<br />

uidated<br />

Let us refer to <strong>the</strong>se two conditions as Y 1,it<br />

=1<strong>and</strong> Y 2,it<br />

=1,<br />

<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>.<br />

respectively, so that Y it<br />

Y 1,it<br />

Then<br />

fund <strong>liquidation</strong>, while Y 2,it<br />

of<br />

τ =t+1<br />

τ =t+1<br />

that it is not used because of <strong>self</strong><strong>selection</strong>.<br />

=0says<br />

To disentangle <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong>se two processes, we first rewrite<br />

L iτ<br />

is a weight factor. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, it follows that<br />

f(r i,t+1, ..., r i,t+s+1|Ω t<br />

)=<br />

∫<br />

w it<br />

f(r i,t+1, ..., r i,t+s+1,z it<br />

|Ω t<br />

,Y it<br />

=1)dz it<br />

, (7)<br />

z<br />

adjusted to recover <strong>the</strong> distribution of returns unconditional upon Y it<br />

=<br />

which is what we are really <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong>. If we are will<strong>in</strong>g to assume<br />

1,<br />

<strong>the</strong> denom<strong>in</strong>ator of (6) does not depend upon r i,t+1, ..., r i,t+s+1<br />

directly,<br />

that<br />

reduce to<br />

it = P {Y it<br />

=1|Ω t<br />

}<br />

w<br />

{Y it<br />

=1|Ω t<br />

,z it<br />

} . (8)<br />

P<br />

= Y 1,it<br />

Y 2,it<br />

. Referr<strong>in</strong>gto<strong>the</strong>twob<strong>in</strong>arychoicemodels<br />

specified above, it holds that<br />

∏ t+s+1<br />

Y 1,it<br />

=<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

∏ t+s+1<br />

Y 2,it =<br />

S iτ .<br />

=0says that fund i is not used <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> analysis <strong>in</strong> period t because<br />

15


If w 2,it<br />

implies <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> if w 1,it<br />

≠1<strong>and</strong> this is <strong>the</strong> case analyzed<br />

<strong>liquidation</strong><br />

Baquero, ter Horst <strong>and</strong> Verbeek (2005). In this paper, we disentangle<br />

by<br />

two sources of <strong>bias</strong> by identify<strong>in</strong>g both sets of weights <strong>and</strong> apply<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

with one weight or <strong>the</strong>ir product. The correction for <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong><br />

corrections<br />

application of <strong>the</strong> above<br />

The<br />

weights allows us to determ<strong>in</strong>e to what extent we get different<br />

correction<br />

if we only correct for <strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong> due to <strong>liquidation</strong>, assum<strong>in</strong>g<br />

results<br />

is r<strong>and</strong>om.<br />

<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong><br />

identify <strong>the</strong> weights (<strong>and</strong> to derive (8)) we need to assume that <strong>the</strong><br />

To<br />

do not depend upon future, potentially unobserved returns.<br />

probabilities<br />

we assume that <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>and</strong> fund <strong>liquidation</strong> are mutually<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>r,<br />

events, <strong>and</strong> both describe “absorb<strong>in</strong>g states”. That is, once a fund<br />

exclusive<br />

Then <strong>the</strong> denom<strong>in</strong>ator of w 1,it<br />

P {Y 1,it =1|Ω t ,z it } = (10)<br />

similarly for w 2,it . The right h<strong>and</strong> side probabilities are described by<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

probit model <strong>in</strong> (3) provided <strong>the</strong> appropriate functional form (<strong>and</strong> con-<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

variables) are chosen <strong>in</strong> x it . Consequently, consistent estimation<br />

dition<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>the</strong> b<strong>in</strong>ary choice models for <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> allows us to<br />

of<br />

consistent estimators for <strong>the</strong> two sets of weights, which enables us<br />

obta<strong>in</strong><br />

correct for <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> due to <strong>the</strong>se two processes <strong>and</strong> separate <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

to<br />

Statistically, equation (9) also holds with <strong>the</strong> role of Y1,it <strong>and</strong> Y2,it reversed, so that<br />

8<br />

correction for <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong> would be conditional upon <strong>the</strong> fund not stopp<strong>in</strong>g re-<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

Given that exist<strong>in</strong>g literature (Baquero, ter Horst <strong>and</strong> Verbeek, 2005) assumes<br />

port<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

is exogenous (w2,it =1), <strong>the</strong> most natural order<strong>in</strong>g is employed here.<br />

<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong><br />

(8) as<br />

{Y it<br />

=1|Ω t<br />

}<br />

P<br />

{Y it =1|Ω t ,z it } = (9)<br />

P<br />

w it<br />

=<br />

{Y 2,it<br />

=1|Ω t<br />

,Y 1,it<br />

=1}<br />

P<br />

{Y 2,it<br />

=1|Ω t<br />

,z it<br />

,Y 1,it<br />

=1} × P {Y 1,it<br />

=1|Ω t<br />

}<br />

P<br />

=<br />

P {Y 1,it<br />

=1|Ω t<br />

,z it<br />

}<br />

= w 2,it w 1,it .<br />

1for all i, t, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> is exogenous <strong>and</strong> does not lead<br />

=<br />

<strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> <strong>in</strong> measures for performance (persistence). In this case,<br />

to<br />

is conditional upon <strong>the</strong> fund not liquidat<strong>in</strong>g. 8<br />

stops report<strong>in</strong>g to TASS, it will not return <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> database at a later stage.<br />

can be determ<strong>in</strong>ed from <strong>the</strong> b<strong>in</strong>ary choice<br />

model as<br />

P {L i,t+1<br />

=1|r it<br />

,r i,t−1, ..., x i,t+1}...P {L i,t+s+1<br />

=1|r i,t+s,r i,t+s−1,...,x i,t+s+1}<br />

16


performance decile), it is most convenient to use a simple nonparametric<br />

past<br />

(see below).<br />

approach<br />

studies on <strong>the</strong> behavior of <strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> funds have shown<br />

Empirical<br />

money-flows chase past performance (see, e.g., Agarwal, Daniel <strong>and</strong><br />

that<br />

2003, or Baquero <strong>and</strong> Verbeek, 2006). Moreover, several recent studies<br />

Naik,<br />

document some evidence of persistence <strong>in</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> fund performance at<br />

horizons (see, e.g., Agarwal <strong>and</strong> Naik, 2000, Bares, Gibson <strong>and</strong><br />

quarterly<br />

2003, Boyson <strong>and</strong> Cooper, 2004), while at longer horizons <strong>the</strong> re-<br />

Gyger,<br />

are more ambiguous (see, e.g., Brown, Goetzmann <strong>and</strong> Ibbotson, 1999,<br />

sults<br />

<strong>and</strong> Goetzmann, 2003, Kosowski, Naik <strong>and</strong> Teo, 2006). Apparently,<br />

Brown<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestors take <strong>in</strong>to account that persistence is ma<strong>in</strong>ly a short term phenomenon,<br />

if<br />

<strong>look</strong><strong>in</strong>g at past performance provides potentially valuable <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

<strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>hedge</strong> funds. However, while all <strong>the</strong> above mentioned studies<br />

for<br />

performance persistence of <strong>hedge</strong> funds control for <strong>the</strong> effects of survivor-<br />

on<br />

<strong>bias</strong>, none of <strong>the</strong>m corrects for <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> due to fund <strong>liquidation</strong><br />

ship<br />

<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>. Baquero, ter Horst <strong>and</strong> Verbeek (2005) correct for <strong>look</strong>-<br />

or<br />

<strong>bias</strong> due to <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d positive persistence at horizons of<br />

<strong>ahead</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> four quarters, although <strong>the</strong> statistical significance is weak. In <strong>the</strong><br />

one<br />

section we extended <strong>the</strong> methodology of <strong>the</strong> latter paper to allow<br />

previous<br />

to disentangle <strong>the</strong> effects of <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong>. In<br />

us<br />

section we will apply this method on analyz<strong>in</strong>g performance persistence<br />

this<br />

<strong>hedge</strong> funds, <strong>and</strong> exam<strong>in</strong>e whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong>es due to <strong>liquidation</strong><br />

of<br />

<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> offset each o<strong>the</strong>r.<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

we will exam<strong>in</strong>e performance persistence <strong>in</strong> raw returns by exam-<br />

First,<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r w<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g funds over <strong>the</strong> last two or four quarters are more<br />

<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

to be top performers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> future. We follow a similar procedure as<br />

likely<br />

ter Horst <strong>and</strong> Verbeek (2005), by dist<strong>in</strong>guish<strong>in</strong>g a rank<strong>in</strong>g period<br />

Baquero,<br />

The<br />

oftwoorfourquarters<strong>and</strong>anevaluationperiodoftwoorfourquarters.<br />

based on past performance is broken down <strong>in</strong>to ten deciles (decile<br />

rank<strong>in</strong>g<br />

conta<strong>in</strong>s <strong>the</strong> past w<strong>in</strong>ners), <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> subsequent evaluation period we<br />

10<br />

upon performance measures <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir persistence. To estimate <strong>the</strong><br />

effects<br />

<strong>in</strong> (9) when Ω t<br />

takesonalimitednumberofdifferentvalues(e.g.<br />

numerator<br />

4 Persistence <strong>in</strong> Hedge <strong>Fund</strong> Performance<br />

calculate <strong>the</strong> average returns of each of <strong>the</strong>se deciles. The procedure is re-<br />

17


over <strong>the</strong> entire sample period, mov<strong>in</strong>g forward by one quarter at <strong>the</strong><br />

peated<br />

<strong>and</strong> adjust<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> sample by <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> funds that have a sufficiently<br />

time<br />

return history. <strong>Fund</strong>-of-funds are excluded to avoid double count<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

long<br />

avoid backfill<strong>in</strong>g <strong>bias</strong>, returns are only used <strong>in</strong> this exercise if <strong>the</strong> fund<br />

To<br />

hasahistoryofatleastfourquarters.<br />

of all, <strong>in</strong> order to prevent spurious performance persistence patterns<br />

First<br />

are due to <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> (see, e.g. Carpenter <strong>and</strong> Lynch, 1999),<br />

that<br />

apply <strong>the</strong> correction method as <strong>in</strong>troduced by ter Horst, Nijman <strong>and</strong><br />

we<br />

we repeat <strong>the</strong> analysis of Baquero, ter Horst<br />

Basically,<br />

Verbeek (2005) by multiply<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> performance measure (e.g. average<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

over <strong>the</strong> rank<strong>in</strong>g period) with a estimated weight factor ŵ 1,it which is<br />

return<br />

ratio of an unconditional non-<strong>liquidation</strong> probability <strong>and</strong> a conditional<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

probability. The latter probability can be obta<strong>in</strong>ed from our<br />

non-<strong>liquidation</strong><br />

<strong>liquidation</strong> process reported <strong>in</strong> Section 3. Let<br />

estimated<br />

( ∑ 6<br />

1 + = ˆγ 1j r i,t−j<br />

+ x ′ )<br />

it<br />

ˆβ 1 ˆα Φ<br />

j=1<br />

<strong>the</strong> estimated (conditional) probability that fund i does not liquidate<br />

denote<br />

period t, where Φ denotes <strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard normal distribution function.<br />

<strong>in</strong><br />

Then <strong>the</strong> denom<strong>in</strong>ator of w 1,it<br />

∏t+s+1<br />

τ =t+1 ˆp iτ<br />

, (12)<br />

s = 4(quarters) <strong>in</strong> case of annual persistence. The unconditional<br />

where<br />

is equal to <strong>the</strong> ratio of funds that were not liquidated dur<strong>in</strong>g<br />

probability<br />

rank<strong>in</strong>g period <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> number of funds present at <strong>the</strong> beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

For <strong>the</strong> evaluation period, we compute average returns with<strong>in</strong> each<br />

period.<br />

aga<strong>in</strong> weighted by ŵ 1,it where <strong>the</strong> numerator now corresponds to <strong>the</strong><br />

decile,<br />

of survived funds <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> correspond<strong>in</strong>g decile.<br />

proportion<br />

we correct for <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong> by multiply<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> performance<br />

Next,<br />

with a second weight factor w 2,it . Thisfactoris<strong>the</strong>ratioof<strong>the</strong><br />

measure<br />

probability of non-<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> (conditional upon not be<strong>in</strong>g liquidated),<br />

conditional<br />

<strong>and</strong> an unconditional non-<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> probability (conditional<br />

not be<strong>in</strong>g liquidated). The conditional probability can be obta<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

upon<br />

<strong>the</strong> estimated <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> process of Section 3. The unconditional<br />

from<br />

Verbeek (2001).<br />

ˆp it<br />

= ˆP {L it<br />

=1|r i,t−1,r i,t−2, ..., x it<br />

} =<br />

(11)<br />

<strong>in</strong>(9)isestimatedas<br />

18


is now equal to <strong>the</strong> ratio of <strong>the</strong> number of funds that were not<br />

probability<br />

m<strong>in</strong>us those that were liquidated dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> rank<strong>in</strong>g period, <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>self</strong>-selected<br />

number of funds present at <strong>the</strong> beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> rank<strong>in</strong>g period m<strong>in</strong>us<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

that were liquidated dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> rank<strong>in</strong>g period. Similarly, we correct<br />

those<br />

average returns over <strong>the</strong> evaluation period once more, but adjust<strong>in</strong>g for<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

fact that <strong>the</strong> unconditional probabilities are now conditional upon <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

decile dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> rank<strong>in</strong>g period.<br />

fund’s<br />

results of <strong>the</strong> above exercises are provided <strong>in</strong> Tables 5 <strong>and</strong> 6 for<br />

The<br />

two-quarter <strong>and</strong> four-quarter horizon, respectively, <strong>and</strong> summarized <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

1<strong>and</strong> 2. We report <strong>the</strong> empirical persistence of raw returns at bi-<br />

Figures<br />

<strong>and</strong> annual horizons, without any correction (raw returns), with a<br />

quarterly<br />

for <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> due to <strong>liquidation</strong> (corrected returns) <strong>and</strong> with<br />

correction<br />

correction for <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> due to both <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong><br />

a<br />

corrected returns). All estimates are based on <strong>the</strong> full sample of<br />

(double<br />

results are remarkable. First of all at a bi-quarterly as well as an<br />

The<br />

horizon we observe evidence of a persistence pattern which is without<br />

annual<br />

Subsequent period performance<br />

0.3000<br />

0.2500<br />

0.2000<br />

0.1500<br />

0.1000<br />

0.0500<br />

0.0000<br />

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10<br />

Initial period rank<br />

raw returns<br />

corrected returns<br />

double corrected returns<br />

Figure 1: Two-quarterly persistence <strong>in</strong> raw returns<br />

<strong>hedge</strong> funds, exclud<strong>in</strong>g fund-of-funds.<br />

corrections (raw returns) slightly J-shaped. As discussed <strong>in</strong> Hendricks, Patel<br />

19


5: Persistence Estimates (Raw returns)<br />

Table<br />

performance (raw returns)<br />

Average<br />

Two-Quarters<br />

(2) (3) (1) - (3)<br />

(1)<br />

non corrected corrected double corrected<br />

Decile<br />

0.1284 0.1139 0.1090 0.0193<br />

1(losers)<br />

2 0.1278 0.1253 0.1250 0.0028<br />

3 0.1308 0.1345 0.1356 −0.0048<br />

4 0.1302 0.1322 0.1333 −0.0031<br />

5 0.1230 0.1297 0.1314 −0.0085<br />

6 0.1492 0.1510 0.1503 −0.0011<br />

7 0.1602 0.1650 0.1694 −0.0091<br />

8 0.1848 0.1892 0.1891 −0.0042<br />

9 0.2112 0.2090 0.2095 0.0017<br />

quarter, funds are sorted <strong>in</strong>to ten rank portfolios based on <strong>the</strong>ir previous<br />

Each<br />

Next, average returns over <strong>the</strong> next two quarters are computed, for<br />

two-quarters.<br />

decile. Us<strong>in</strong>g returns from 1994-2000, this produces a time-series for each<br />

each<br />

of 21 average two-quarter returns. The numbers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> table are <strong>the</strong> annu-<br />

decile<br />

time-series averages <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir st<strong>and</strong>ard errors <strong>in</strong> paren<strong>the</strong>ses. The st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

alized<br />

are corrected for autocorrelation based on <strong>the</strong> Newey-West approach. The<br />

errors<br />

figures employ a weight<strong>in</strong>g procedure to elim<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong>, <strong>and</strong><br />

corrected<br />

double corrected employ a weight<strong>in</strong>g procedure to elim<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

(0.0794) (0.0932) (0.0987) (0.0229)<br />

(0.0335) (0.0374) (0.0380) (0.0067)<br />

(0.0291) (0.0300) (0.0298) (0.0046)<br />

(0.0242) (0.0246) (0.0246) (0.0029)<br />

(0.0218) (0.0249) (0.0253) (0.0058)<br />

(0.0255) (0.0258) (0.0242) (0.0061)<br />

(0.0296) (0.0286) (0.0310) (0.0068)<br />

(0.0416) (0.0450) (0.0445) (0.0072)<br />

(0.0529) (0.0512) (0.0518) (0.0054)<br />

10 (w<strong>in</strong>ners) 0.2448 0.2278 0.2283 0.0165<br />

(0.0810) (0.0798) (0.0800) (0.0108)<br />

w<strong>in</strong>ners - losers 0.1164 0.1139 0.1193 −0.0028<br />

(0.0918) (0.0984) (0.1027) (0.0247)<br />

<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong>.<br />

20


6: Persistence Estimates (Raw returns)<br />

Table<br />

performance (raw returns)<br />

Average<br />

Four-Quarters<br />

(2) (3) (1) - (3)<br />

(1)<br />

non corrected corrected double corrected<br />

Decile<br />

0.1601 0.1018 0.0832 0.0769<br />

1(losers)<br />

2 0.1658 0.1446 0.1374 0.0284<br />

3 0.1459 0.1262 0.1216 0.0243<br />

4 0.1451 0.1328 0.1318 0.0132<br />

5 0.1418 0.1359 0.1345 0.0073<br />

6 0.1342 0.1304 0.1280 0.0062<br />

7 0.1403 0.1361 0.1327 0.0076<br />

8 0.1565 0.1566 0.1580 −0.0015<br />

9 0.1900 0.1840 0.1798 0.0102<br />

quarter, funds are sorted <strong>in</strong>to ten rank portfolios based on <strong>the</strong>ir previous<br />

Each<br />

returns, respectively. Next, average returns over <strong>the</strong> next four quar-<br />

four-quarter<br />

are computed, for each decile. Us<strong>in</strong>g returns from 1994-2000, this produces a<br />

ters<br />

for each decile of 17 (overlapp<strong>in</strong>g) average four-quarter returns. The<br />

time-series<br />

<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> table are <strong>the</strong> annualized time-series averages <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

numbers<br />

<strong>in</strong> paren<strong>the</strong>ses. The st<strong>and</strong>ard errors are corrected for autocorrelation based<br />

errors<br />

<strong>the</strong> Newey-West approach. The corrected figures employ a weight<strong>in</strong>g procedure<br />

on<br />

to elim<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> double corrected employ a weight<strong>in</strong>g<br />

(0.0911) (0.0946) (0.0956) (0.0207)<br />

(0.0600) (0.0545) (0.0526) (0.0141)<br />

(0.0455) (0.0404) (0.0401) (0.0134)<br />

(0.0387) (0.0370) (0.0351) (0.0081)<br />

(0.0252) (0.0246) (0.0271) (0.0054)<br />

(0.0318) (0.0349) (0.0366) (0.0090)<br />

(0.0381) (0.0398) (0.0397) (0.0099)<br />

(0.0325) (0.0337) (0.0337) (0.0085)<br />

(0.0468) (0.0491) (0.0461) (0.0094)<br />

10 (w<strong>in</strong>ners) 0.2029 0.1862 0.1838 0.0191<br />

(0.1016) (0.0979) (0.1001) (0.0120)<br />

w<strong>in</strong>ners - losers 0.0428 0.0844 0.1006 −0.0578<br />

(0.0693) (0.0724) (0.0713) (0.0186)<br />

procedure to elim<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong>.<br />

21


Zeckhauser (1997) <strong>and</strong> ter Horst, Nijman <strong>and</strong> Verbeek (2001) such a<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

could be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong>. If we correct for <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong><br />

pattern<br />

<strong>the</strong> expected returns on <strong>the</strong> lower deciles are significantly reduced <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>bias</strong><br />

J-shape flattens. As a result, <strong>the</strong> relationship between past <strong>and</strong> future<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

expected returns on a zero<br />

The<br />

portfolio that is long <strong>in</strong> w<strong>in</strong>ners (decile 10) <strong>and</strong> short <strong>in</strong> losers<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

with a t-value of −3.11. At <strong>the</strong> bi-quarterly horizon, <strong>the</strong> w<strong>in</strong>nerloser<br />

significant<br />

portfolio has an expected return of 11.9%, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> correction for <strong>look</strong>-<br />

<strong>bias</strong> has very little impact. Brown, Goetzmann <strong>and</strong> Ibbotson (1999),<br />

<strong>ahead</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> Naik (2000), <strong>and</strong> Bares, Gibson <strong>and</strong> Gyger (2003), also f<strong>in</strong>d<br />

Agarwal<br />

of a persistence pattern at a short term horizon, while <strong>the</strong> pattern<br />

evidence<br />

less strong at longer horizons. However, note that <strong>the</strong>se studies do not<br />

is<br />

for <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong>, <strong>and</strong> that without corrections, average returns<br />

correct<br />

be overestimated by as much as 7.7% (decile 1, annual horizon). For<br />

may<br />

discussion on correct<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> we refer to Baquero,<br />

additional<br />

Horst <strong>and</strong> Verbeek (2005).<br />

ter<br />

Subsequent period performance<br />

0.2500<br />

0.2000<br />

0.1500<br />

0.1000<br />

0.0500<br />

0.0000<br />

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10<br />

Initial period rank<br />

raw returns<br />

corrected returns<br />

double corrected returns<br />

Figure 2: Four-quarterly persistence <strong>in</strong> raw returns.<br />

performance becomes more monotonic.<br />

1), is approximately 10.0% at <strong>the</strong> annual horizon, while it is only 4.3%<br />

(decile<br />

no correction for <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> is applied. The difference is statistically<br />

if<br />

The most strik<strong>in</strong>g result is that <strong>the</strong> correction for <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> due to<br />

22


works <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> same direction as <strong>the</strong> one for <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong>, <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong><br />

streng<strong>the</strong>ns <strong>the</strong> positive persistence patterns. For most of <strong>the</strong> deciles<br />

thus<br />

see that <strong>the</strong> two <strong>bias</strong>es have <strong>the</strong> same sign. Apparently, <strong>the</strong> majority<br />

we<br />

funds that stop report<strong>in</strong>g voluntarily have lower returns than those that<br />

of<br />

to report, consistent with Tables 1<strong>and</strong> 4. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, <strong>the</strong>re is no<br />

cont<strong>in</strong>ue<br />

effect that reduces <strong>the</strong> <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong> due to relatively<br />

counterbalanc<strong>in</strong>g<br />

funds that close for new <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>and</strong> stop report<strong>in</strong>g. Thus,<br />

successful<br />

Ackermann, McEnally <strong>and</strong> Ravenscraft (1999) argue that positive <strong>and</strong><br />

while<br />

survival-related <strong>bias</strong>es may offset each o<strong>the</strong>r, this does not apply to<br />

negative<br />

<strong>bias</strong> due to <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>. Because this conclusion<br />

<strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong><br />

be related to <strong>the</strong> way we def<strong>in</strong>e <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> cases, <strong>the</strong><br />

may<br />

section provides some robustness checks.<br />

next<br />

mentioned before, it is difficult to p<strong>in</strong> down what exactly <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong><br />

As<br />

for <strong>hedge</strong> funds. For example, a fund may decide to stop report<strong>in</strong>g<br />

means<br />

it is too small <strong>and</strong> subsequently decide to liquidate several quarters<br />

because<br />

Our classification of attrition cases so far was determ<strong>in</strong>ed by <strong>the</strong><br />

later.<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation provided by TASS <strong>and</strong>, when necessary, by <strong>the</strong> sign<br />

qualitative<br />

<strong>the</strong> fund’s cash flows <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> last available year. We have experimented<br />

of<br />

alternative classification procedures, result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> qualitatively similar<br />

with<br />

when we analyze performance persistence. To be precise, <strong>the</strong> post-<br />

results<br />

expected returns for all deciles after correct<strong>in</strong>g for both <strong>liquidation</strong><br />

rank<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong> are highly robust, although <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual magnitude<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> two <strong>bias</strong>es depends upon <strong>the</strong> exact classification scheme. The latter<br />

of<br />

can be attributed to <strong>the</strong> problem that it is not unambiguous whe<strong>the</strong>r<br />

f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g<br />

given situation should be classified as <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> or <strong>liquidation</strong>.<br />

a<br />

this section we report <strong>the</strong> results when we classify disappearance rea-<br />

In<br />

2 (“at fund manager’s request”) <strong>and</strong> 4 (“unknown”) <strong>in</strong>to positive <strong>and</strong><br />

sons<br />

events by us<strong>in</strong>g additional <strong>in</strong>formation on fund flows <strong>and</strong> returns.<br />

negative<br />

particular, we classify a case as “<strong>liquidation</strong>” when a fund experiences<br />

In<br />

cash flows <strong>in</strong> its last year, has negative cumulative returns over <strong>the</strong><br />

negative<br />

year <strong>and</strong> has negative returns for each of <strong>the</strong> last two quarters of its<br />

last<br />

period. All o<strong>the</strong>r cases are treated as “<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>”. Because<br />

report<strong>in</strong>g<br />

5 Robustness checks<br />

empirical studies report that flows are highly l<strong>in</strong>ked to past performance<br />

23


Daniel <strong>and</strong> Naik, 2003, Baquero <strong>and</strong> Verbeek, 2006), this may<br />

(Agarwal,<br />

us to better identify funds that are expected to liquidate <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> future<br />

allow<br />

of large negative flows after <strong>the</strong>ir report<strong>in</strong>g period). Compared<br />

(because<br />

<strong>the</strong> previous classification, 19 cases move from <strong>the</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> to <strong>the</strong><br />

to<br />

b<strong>in</strong>.<br />

<strong>liquidation</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> classification of cases is based on past returns, this obviously<br />

Because<br />

hassomeimpactupon<strong>the</strong>coefficientestimatesfor<strong>the</strong>laggedreturns<strong>in</strong><br />

b<strong>in</strong>ary probit models expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>. For <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

model <strong>the</strong> cumulative estimated impact of past returns <strong>in</strong>creases<br />

<strong>liquidation</strong><br />

from 3.394 (Table 3) to 3.775, not tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to account <strong>the</strong> underwater<br />

slightly<br />

For <strong>the</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> model, <strong>the</strong> cumulative impact reduces from<br />

dummy.<br />

(Table 4) to 3.364. Apart from this, <strong>the</strong> estimation results for <strong>the</strong>se two<br />

4.386<br />

with <strong>and</strong> without net asset value (available upon request), are not<br />

models,<br />

different from before. Note that, even with this new classification,<br />

noticeably<br />

probability of <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> is negatively (<strong>and</strong> statistically significantly)<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

to past performance.<br />

related<br />

use <strong>the</strong>se new models to correct <strong>the</strong> persistence analysis for <strong>look</strong><strong>ahead</strong><br />

We<br />

<strong>bias</strong> due to <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>. As before, <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong><br />

limited impact at <strong>the</strong> two-quarter horizon, reported <strong>in</strong> Table 7, but substantial<br />

has<br />

impact at <strong>the</strong> four-quarter horizon, reported <strong>in</strong> Table 8. Given that<br />

past returns are used to classify a case as <strong>liquidation</strong>, it is not surpris<strong>in</strong>g<br />

poor<br />

see that <strong>the</strong> <strong>bias</strong> due to fund <strong>liquidation</strong> has <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong> magnitude, at<br />

to<br />

cost of <strong>the</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong>. However, <strong>the</strong> expected returns for each of<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

deciles, after correct<strong>in</strong>g for both sources of <strong>bias</strong>, are virtually <strong>the</strong> same as<br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

reported <strong>in</strong> Tables 5 <strong>and</strong> 6. To some extent this reflects <strong>the</strong> ambiguity<br />

those<br />

classify<strong>in</strong>g a case as ei<strong>the</strong>r “<strong>liquidation</strong>” or “<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>”. Two conclu-<br />

<strong>in</strong><br />

are clear, however. First, no matter how we def<strong>in</strong>e it, <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> has<br />

sions<br />

offsett<strong>in</strong>g impact upon <strong>the</strong> <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong>. Second, it is <strong>in</strong>appropriate to<br />

no<br />

correct for <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong> while at <strong>the</strong> same time restrict<strong>in</strong>g attention<br />

only<br />

those cases that are classified by TASS as “liquidated”.<br />

to<br />

analyz<strong>in</strong>g <strong>hedge</strong> fund performance <strong>and</strong> its persistence, a multi-period<br />

When<br />

<strong>bias</strong> or <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> may arise if funds attrite from <strong>the</strong> available<br />

sampl<strong>in</strong>g<br />

6 Conclud<strong>in</strong>g remarks<br />

databases due to reasons that relate to <strong>the</strong>ir performance. In this paper, we<br />

24


7: Persistence Estimates (Raw returns), alternative classification<br />

Table<br />

performance (raw returns)<br />

Average<br />

Two-Quarters<br />

(2) (3) (1) - (3)<br />

(1)<br />

non corrected corrected double corrected<br />

Decile<br />

1(losers) 0.1284 0.1094 0.1086 0.0198<br />

2 0.1278 0.1252 0.1248 0.0028<br />

3 0.1308 0.1344 0.1354 −0.0046<br />

4 0.1302 0.1318 0.1332 −0.0030<br />

5 0.1230 0.1290 0.1310 −0.0080<br />

6 0.1492 0.1510 0.1516 −0.0024<br />

7 0.1602 0.1658 0.1682 −0.0080<br />

8 0.1848 0.1890 0.1886 −0.0038<br />

9 0.2112 0.2078 0.2100 0.0012<br />

quarter, funds are sorted <strong>in</strong>to ten rank portfolios based on <strong>the</strong>ir previous<br />

Each<br />

Next, average returns over <strong>the</strong> next two quarters are computed, for<br />

two-quarters.<br />

decile. Us<strong>in</strong>g returns from 1994-2000, this produces a time-series for each<br />

each<br />

of 21 average two-quarter returns. The numbers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> table are <strong>the</strong> annu-<br />

decile<br />

time-series averages <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir st<strong>and</strong>ard errors <strong>in</strong> paren<strong>the</strong>ses. The st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

alized<br />

are corrected for autocorrelation based on <strong>the</strong> Newey-West approach. The<br />

errors<br />

figures employ a weight<strong>in</strong>g procedure to elim<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong>, <strong>and</strong><br />

corrected<br />

double corrected employ a weight<strong>in</strong>g procedure to elim<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>bias</strong>. This table is based on an alternative classification of cases as<br />

<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong><br />

or “<strong>self</strong>-selected” (see text).<br />

"liquidated”<br />

(0.0794) (0.0967) (0.0990) (0.0233)<br />

(0.0335) (0.0375) (0.0280) (0.0066)<br />

(0.0291) (0.0301) (0.0297) (0.0045)<br />

(0.0242) (0.0246) (0.0257) (0.0028)<br />

(0.0218) (0.0252) (0.0259) (0.0062)<br />

(0.0255) (0.0235) (0.0238) (0.0064)<br />

(0.0296) (0.0303) (0.0310) (0.0069)<br />

(0.0416) (0.0448) (0.0447) (0.0072)<br />

(0.0529) (0.0506) (0.0516) (0.0061)<br />

10 (w<strong>in</strong>ners) 0.2448 0.2288 0.2288 0.0160<br />

(0.0810) (0.0806) (0.0799) (0.0109)<br />

w<strong>in</strong>ners - losers 0.1164 0.1194 0.1204 −0.0040<br />

(0.0918) (0.1018) (0.1031) (0.0250)<br />

25


8: Persistence Estimates (Raw returns), alternative classification<br />

Table<br />

performance (raw returns)<br />

Average<br />

Four-Quarters<br />

(2) (3) (1) - (3)<br />

(1)<br />

non corrected corrected double corrected<br />

Decile<br />

1(losers) 0.1601 0.0922 0.0826 0.0775<br />

2 0.1658 0.1424 0.1370 0.0288<br />

3 0.1459 0.1235 0.1213 0.0246<br />

4 0.1451 0.1323 0.1321 0.0129<br />

5 0.1418 0.1372 0.1344 0.0074<br />

6 0.1342 0.1288 0.1290 0.0052<br />

7 0.1403 0.1340 0.1341 0.0090<br />

8 0.1565 0.1556 0.1581 −0.0016<br />

9 0.1900 0.1835 0.1806 0.0093<br />

quarter, funds are sorted <strong>in</strong>to ten rank portfolios based on <strong>the</strong>ir previous<br />

Each<br />

returns, respectively. Next, average returns over <strong>the</strong> next four quar-<br />

four-quarter<br />

are computed, for each decile. Us<strong>in</strong>g returns from 1994-2000, this produces a<br />

ters<br />

for each decile of 17 (overlapp<strong>in</strong>g) average four-quarter returns. The<br />

time-series<br />

<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> table are <strong>the</strong> annualized time-series averages <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

numbers<br />

<strong>in</strong> paren<strong>the</strong>ses. The st<strong>and</strong>ard errors are corrected for autocorrelation based<br />

errors<br />

<strong>the</strong> Newey-West approach. The corrected figures employ a weight<strong>in</strong>g procedure<br />

on<br />

to elim<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>bias</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> double corrected employ a weight<strong>in</strong>g<br />

to elim<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong>. This table is based on<br />

procedure<br />

alternative classification of cases as "liquidated” or “<strong>self</strong>-selected” (see text).<br />

an<br />

(0.0911) (0.0960) (0.0957) (0.0210)<br />

(0.0600) (0.0542) (0.0528) (0.0142)<br />

(0.0455) (0.0408) (0.0400) (0.0134)<br />

(0.0387) (0.0365) (0.0350) (0.0081)<br />

(0.0252) (0.0242) (0.0270) (0.0054)<br />

(0.0318) (0.0369) (0.0361) (0.0089)<br />

(0.0381) (0.0396) (0.0400) (0.0095)<br />

(0.0325) (0.0337) (0.0339) (0.0087)<br />

(0.0468) (0.0479) (0.0471) (0.0097)<br />

10 (w<strong>in</strong>ners) 0.2029 0.1844 0.1824 0.0204<br />

(0.1016) (0.1006) (0.0995) (0.0131)<br />

w<strong>in</strong>ners - losers 0.0428 0.0922 0.0998 −0.0570<br />

(0.0693) (0.0728) (0.0720) (0.0188)<br />

26


two important reasons why funds may disappear from <strong>hedge</strong> fund<br />

consider<br />

First, funds may liquidate or close down due to <strong>the</strong>ir poor perfor-<br />

databases.<br />

<strong>and</strong>, second, <strong>hedge</strong> fund managers may voluntary stop report<strong>in</strong>g to a<br />

mance,<br />

vendor (<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>). In this paper we empirically <strong>in</strong>vestigate <strong>the</strong><br />

database<br />

of fund <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong>, <strong>and</strong> analyze <strong>the</strong> impact<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>ants<br />

<strong>the</strong>se two process upon persistence measures of <strong>hedge</strong> fund performance.<br />

of<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation from <strong>the</strong> TASS database, cover<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> period 1994-<br />

Us<strong>in</strong>g<br />

we f<strong>in</strong>d that both <strong>liquidation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> are more likely for<br />

2000,<br />

funds that have a poor return history. While <strong>the</strong> relationship is somewhat<br />

<strong>hedge</strong><br />

stronger for <strong>the</strong> <strong>liquidation</strong> process, this implies that <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong><br />

to <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> affects persistence measures <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> same direction as<br />

due<br />

<strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> due to fund <strong>liquidation</strong>. Consequently, double correct-<br />

does<br />

persistence tables leads to a stronger persistence pattern than obta<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Baquero, ter Horst <strong>and</strong> Verbeek (2005), where <strong>look</strong>-<strong>ahead</strong> <strong>bias</strong> due to<br />

<strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> annual horizon, <strong>the</strong> expected<br />

At<br />

return on a w<strong>in</strong>ner m<strong>in</strong>us loser portfolio, based upon previous year<br />

excess<br />

is close to 10% when both <strong>bias</strong>es are taken <strong>in</strong>to account, while it<br />

returns,<br />

only 4.3% if no correction is employed. These <strong>bias</strong>es are almost entirely<br />

is<br />

<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> bottom decile, where expected returns may be significantly<br />

located<br />

by almost 8% per year.<br />

overestimated<br />

<strong>liquidation</strong> is <strong>the</strong> focus of <strong>in</strong>terest.<br />

27


appendix conta<strong>in</strong>s <strong>the</strong> estimation results for <strong>the</strong> b<strong>in</strong>ary <strong>liquidation</strong><br />

This<br />

<strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> models, when fund size is excluded from <strong>the</strong> condition<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

These models, estimated over a larger sample, are used to correct for<br />

set.<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> <strong>bias</strong> <strong>in</strong> cases where fund NAV is unobserved.<br />

<strong>liquidation</strong><br />

−0.343 0.363 long/short equity −0.133 0.073<br />

ln(Age) 2 0.061 0.048 managed futures −0.285 0.067<br />

ln(Age)<br />

9: Estimation results <strong>liquidation</strong> model, exclud<strong>in</strong>g net asset value<br />

Table<br />

21297 fund/period observations.<br />

(size);<br />

Appendix<br />

Parameters Estimate Std.error Parameters Estimate Std. Error<br />

<strong>in</strong>tercept 3.986 0.719 offshore −0.110 0.049<br />

r(−1) 1.250 0.201 Incentive Fees −0.008 0.003<br />

r(−2) 1.065 0.216 Mng. Fees −0.018 0.023<br />

r(−3) 1.282 0.217 underwater −0.340 0.063<br />

r(−4) 0.499 0.219 emerg<strong>in</strong>g markets −0.017 0.078<br />

r(−5) 0.252 0.178 equity market neutral −0.162 0.088<br />

r(−6) 0.012 0.162 event driven 0.155 0.102<br />

fixed <strong>in</strong>come arbitrage −0.067 0.200<br />

StDev 0.522 0.352 global macro 0.019 0.174<br />

Loglikelihood: −1817.495 Chi-squared test: 502.38 (DF =41)<br />

pseudoR 2 :0.1214 (p =0.000)<br />

28


0.608 0.340 emerg<strong>in</strong>g markets 0.025 0.128<br />

r(−4)<br />

0.030 0.253 equity market neutral 0.061 0.145<br />

r(−5)<br />

10: Estimation results <strong>self</strong>-<strong>selection</strong> model, exclud<strong>in</strong>g net asset value<br />

Table<br />

20876 fund/period observations.<br />

(size);<br />

Agarwal, V., <strong>and</strong> N.Y. Naik, 2000, Multi-Period Performance Persistence<br />

[2]<br />

Analysis of Hedge <strong>Fund</strong>s, Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>and</strong> Quantitative<br />

Baquero, G., J.R. ter Horst <strong>and</strong> M. Verbeek, 2005, Survival, Look<br />

[4]<br />

Bias <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Persistence <strong>in</strong> Hedge <strong>Fund</strong> Performance, Journal<br />

Ahead<br />

Baquero, G. <strong>and</strong> M. Verbeek, 2006, A Portrait of Hedge <strong>Fund</strong> Investors:<br />

[5]<br />

Performance <strong>and</strong> Smart Money, EFA 2006 Zurich Meet<strong>in</strong>gs,<br />

Flows,<br />

Parameters Estimate Std.error Parameters Estimate Std. Error<br />

<strong>in</strong>tercept 4.107 1.085 offshore 0.104 0.074<br />

r(−1) 1.575 0.343 Incentive Fees −0.013 0.005<br />

r(−2) 1.303 0.347 Mng. Fees −0.049 0.034<br />

r(−3) 0.668 0.325 underwater 0.031 0.112<br />

r(−6) 0.914 0.382 event driven 0.190 0.148<br />

fixed <strong>in</strong>come arbitrage 0.105 0.363<br />

StDev 0.652 0.566 global macro 0.287 0.345<br />

ln(Age) −0.557 0.570 long/short equity −0.117 0.104<br />

ln(Age) 2 0.088 0.075 managed futures −0.043 0.105<br />

Loglikelihood: −693.909 Chi-squared test: 130.71 (DF =41)<br />

pseudoR 2 :0.0861 (p =0.000)<br />

References<br />

Ackermann, C., R. McEnally <strong>and</strong> D. Ravenscraft, 1999, The Performance<br />

[1]<br />

of Hedge <strong>Fund</strong>s: Risk, Return <strong>and</strong> Incentives, Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance,<br />

54, 833-874.<br />

Analysis, 35, 327-342.<br />

Agarwal, V., Daniel, N.D., <strong>and</strong> N.Y. Naik, 2004, Flows, Performance,<br />

[3]<br />

Managerial Incentives <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hedge <strong>Fund</strong> Industry, EFA 2003 Glas-<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

gow Meet<strong>in</strong>gs, available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=424369.<br />

of F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>and</strong> Quantitative Analysis, 40, 493-518.<br />

available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=773384.<br />

29


Berk, J.B. <strong>and</strong> R.C. Green, 2004, Mutual <strong>Fund</strong> Flows <strong>and</strong> Performance<br />

[7]<br />

Rational Markets, Journal of Political Economy, 112, 1269-1295.<br />

<strong>in</strong><br />

Bollen, N.P.B., <strong>and</strong> J.A. Busse, 2005, Short-term Persistence <strong>in</strong> Mutual<br />

[8]<br />

Performance, Review of F<strong>in</strong>ancial Studies, 18, 569 - 597.<br />

<strong>Fund</strong><br />

Boyson, N.M, <strong>and</strong> M.J. Cooper, 2004, Do Hedge <strong>Fund</strong>s Show Performance<br />

[9]<br />

Persistence A New Approach, work<strong>in</strong>g paper, Nor<strong>the</strong>astern<br />

Brown,S.J.,W.N.Goetzmann,R.Ibbotson,<strong>and</strong>S.A.Ross,1992,SurvivorshipBias<strong>in</strong>PerformanceStudies,Review<br />

[10]<br />

of F<strong>in</strong>ancial Studies, 5,<br />

Brown S.J., W.N. Goetzmann <strong>and</strong> R.G. Ibbotson, 1999, Offshore Hedge<br />

[12]<br />

Survival <strong>and</strong> Performance 1989-1995, Journal of Bus<strong>in</strong>ess, 72,<br />

<strong>Fund</strong>s:<br />

Brown S.J., W.N. Goetzmann <strong>and</strong> J. Park, 2001, Careers <strong>and</strong> Survival:<br />

[13]<br />

<strong>and</strong> Risk <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hedge <strong>Fund</strong> <strong>and</strong> CTA Industry, Journal<br />

Competition<br />

Capocci, D. <strong>and</strong> G. Hübner, 2004, Analysis of Hedge <strong>Fund</strong> Performance,<br />

[14]<br />

of Empirical F<strong>in</strong>ance, 11, 55-89.<br />

Journal<br />

Carhart, M.M. 1997, On Persistence <strong>in</strong> Mutual <strong>Fund</strong> Performance,<br />

[15]<br />

of F<strong>in</strong>ance, 52, 57-82.<br />

Journal<br />

Carpenter, J.F., <strong>and</strong> A. Lynch, 1999, Survivorship Bias <strong>and</strong> Attrition<br />

[16]<br />

<strong>in</strong> Measures of Performance Persistence, Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

Effects<br />

Elton, E.J., M.J. Gruber, <strong>and</strong> C.R. Blake, 1996, Survivorship Bias <strong>and</strong><br />

[17]<br />

<strong>Fund</strong> Performance, Review of F<strong>in</strong>ancial Studies, 9, 1097-1120.<br />

Mutual<br />

Bares, P.A., R. Gibson <strong>and</strong> S. Gyger, 2003, Performance <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hedge<br />

[6]<br />

Industry: An Analysis of Short <strong>and</strong> Long Term Persistence, Jour-<br />

<strong>Fund</strong><br />

nal of Alternative Investments, 6,25-41.<br />

University, available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=686572.<br />

553-580.<br />

[11] Brown S.J. <strong>and</strong> W.N. Goetzmann, 2003, Hedge <strong>Fund</strong>s with Style, Journal<br />

of Portfolio Management, 29, 101-112.<br />

91-117.<br />

of F<strong>in</strong>ance, 56, 1869-1886.<br />

Economics, 54, 337-374.<br />

30


Fung, W. <strong>and</strong> D.A. Hsieh, 1997, Empirical Characteristics of Dynamic<br />

[19]<br />

Strategies: The Case of Hedge <strong>Fund</strong>s, Review of F<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

Trad<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Getmansky, M., 2005, The Life cycle of Hedge <strong>Fund</strong>s: <strong>Fund</strong> Flows, Size<br />

[20]<br />

Performance, work<strong>in</strong>g paper, MIT Sloan School of Management.<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

Getmanksy, M., A.W. Lo <strong>and</strong> I. Makarov, 2004, An Econometric Model<br />

[21]<br />

Serial Correlation <strong>and</strong> Illiquidity <strong>in</strong> Hedge <strong>Fund</strong> Returns, Journal of<br />

of<br />

Heckman, J.J., 1979, Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error,<br />

[23]<br />

47, 153-161.<br />

Econometrica,<br />

Hendricks, D., J. Patel, <strong>and</strong> R. Zeckhauser, 1997, The J-shape of performance<br />

[24]<br />

persistence given Survivorship Bias, The Review of Economics<br />

Horst, J.R., ter, Th. Nijman <strong>and</strong> M. Verbeek, 2001, Elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g Look-<br />

[25]<br />

Bias <strong>in</strong> Evaluat<strong>in</strong>g Persistence <strong>in</strong> Mutual <strong>Fund</strong> Performance,<br />

Ahead<br />

Jagannathan, R., A. Malakhov <strong>and</strong> D. Novikov, 2006, Do Hot<br />

[27]<br />

Persist Among Hedge <strong>Fund</strong> Managers An Empirical<br />

H<strong>and</strong>s<br />

NBER Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper W12015, available at SSRN:<br />

Evaluation,<br />

http://ssrn.com/abstract=881249.<br />

Fitzgerald, F. P. Gottschalk, <strong>and</strong> R. Moffitt, 1998, An Analysis of Sample<br />

[18]<br />

Attrition <strong>in</strong> Panel Data: The Michigan Panel Study of Income Dynamics,<br />

Journal of Human Resources, 33, 251-299.<br />

Studies, 10, 275-302.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ancial Economics, 74, 529-609.<br />

Hausman, J.A., <strong>and</strong> D. Wise, 1979. Attrition Bias <strong>in</strong> Experimental <strong>and</strong><br />

[22]<br />

Data: The Gary Income Ma<strong>in</strong>tenance Experiment, Economet-<br />

Panel<br />

rica, 47, 455—473.<br />

<strong>and</strong> Statistics, 79, 161-170.<br />

Journal of Empirical F<strong>in</strong>ance, 8,345-373.<br />

Huij, J. <strong>and</strong> M. Verbeek, 2006, Cross-Sectional Learn<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong><br />

[26]<br />

Persistence <strong>in</strong> Mutual <strong>Fund</strong> Performance, Jour-<br />

Short-Run<br />

nal of Bank<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> F<strong>in</strong>ance, forthcom<strong>in</strong>g; available at SSRN:<br />

http://ssrn.com/abstract=567701.<br />

31


Posthuma, N. <strong>and</strong> P.J. van der Sluis, 2003, A Reality Check<br />

[30]<br />

Hedge <strong>Fund</strong>s Returns, work<strong>in</strong>g paper, available at SSRN:<br />

on<br />

Sirri, E.R., <strong>and</strong> P. Tufano, 1998, Costly Search <strong>and</strong> Mutual <strong>Fund</strong> Flows,<br />

[31]<br />

of F<strong>in</strong>ance, 53, 1589-1622.<br />

Journal<br />

Wermers, R., 2003, Is Money Really “Smart” New Evidence on <strong>the</strong><br />

[33]<br />

between Mutual <strong>Fund</strong> Flows, Manager Behavior, <strong>and</strong> Perfor-<br />

Relation<br />

Persistence, work<strong>in</strong>g paper, University of Maryl<strong>and</strong>, available at<br />

mance<br />

http://ssrn.com/abstract=414420.<br />

SSRN:<br />

Kosowski, R., N.Y. Naik <strong>and</strong> M. Teo, 2006, Do Hedge <strong>Fund</strong>s Deliver<br />

[28]<br />

A Bayesian <strong>and</strong> Bootstrap Analysis, Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ancial Eco-<br />

Alpha<br />

nomics,<br />

[29] Malkiel, B.G. <strong>and</strong> A. Saha, 2005, Hedge <strong>Fund</strong>s: Risk <strong>and</strong> Return, F<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

Analysts Journal, 61, 80-88.<br />

http://ssrn.com/abstract=438840.<br />

ter Horst, J.R. <strong>and</strong> M. Verbeek, 2000, Estimat<strong>in</strong>g Short-Run Persistence<br />

[32]<br />

<strong>in</strong> Mutual <strong>Fund</strong> Performance, The Review of Economics <strong>and</strong> Statistics,<br />

82, 646-655.<br />

32

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!